SlideShare a Scribd company logo
1 of 13
Download to read offline
The role of knowledge sharing and organizational learning in
alliances between competitors
Paavo Ritala; Miia Kosonen
Lappeenranta University of Technology, paavo.ritala@lut.fi
Lappeenranta University of Technology, miia.kosonen@lut.fi
Abstract
The increasing tendency of firms to operate in networks has given rise to the phenomenon of
alliances between competitors (i.e. coopetition). Despite some evidence on the beneficial effects
of coopetition, there is a fundamental paradox involved: knowledge used in cooperation can also
be used in competition. Thus, it is essential to understand what kind of knowledge is shared and
learned by firms in coopetition in order to understand the risks and possibilities involved. To shed
light on this problem, we focus on three types of alliance-related knowledge, which all have
distinct differences in the context of coopetition: first, alliance-specific knowledge can create
potential value to all the participants of a specific alliance; second, alliance-generic knowledge
can help firms to improve operations in all alliances; and third, alliance-external knowledge can
be used in firms’ own operations, which can also be strictly competitive against the partner. To
further contribute to our theoretical field, we analyze how the types of knowledge imply different
levels of risk, trust and control in alliances between competitors.
Keywords
Knowledge sharing, learning, alliance, coopetition, trust, risk, control
Introduction
According to Harbison and Pekar (1998), over 50 per cent of new alliances are formed between
competing firms. This phenomenon of simultaneous competition and cooperation has been
named coopetition (Brandenburger and Nalebuff, 1995; 1996). It has been noted that coopetition
can enhance innovativeness (Quintana-GarcĂ­a and Benavides-Velasco, 2004) and performance
(Luo et al., 2007) with respect to cooperation between non-competitors. This can be explained in
many ways, including the fact that competing firms are able to learn from each other very
effectively (see e.g. Dussauge et al., 2000).
There is, however, a fundamental paradox concerning the role of knowledge sharing in
coopetition. According to several authors (Bengtsson and Kock, 2000; Loebbecke et al., 1998),
knowledge can be used for the purpose of both cooperation and competition, which makes its role
problematic. The nature of coopetition makes the issue of “what to share with whom, when, and
under what conditions paramount in a firm’s effort to achieve a sustainable competitive
advantage” (Loebbecke et al., 1998, p. 218). Hence, in order to create value in alliances between
competitors, knowledge sharing between firms must be carefully managed. Especially when
competing firms are concerned, there is always a risk of unintended knowledge spillover which
might hamper the efforts of knowledge sharing and learning, and furthermore mutual value
creation. However, learning in alliances is not always straightforward, because firms are able to
learn many types of knowledge which all have different purposes (see e.g. Das and Kumar, 2007;
Inkpen, 2000).
Several studies have tried to explain how alliances between competitors should be managed in
order to solve the dilemmas of knowledge sharing. These studies have mainly focused on
governance issues or firm-level strategizing (Loebbecke et al., 1998; McGill, 2007; Oxley and
Sampson, 2004). Some studies recognize the risks and motivations that are connected to sharing
and learning knowledge between competitors (e.g. Hamel, 1991; Soekijad and Andriessen, 2003).
However, none of these studies have explicitly analyzed how different types of knowledge and
learning affect the management of coopetitive relationship. Thus, we focus on the question: what
is the role of different types of alliance-related knowledge in coopetitive relationships?
Methodologically, our study is a theoretical literature review, which contributes to the coopetition
literature (and to alliance literature in general) by explicating the role of different types of
alliance-related knowledge, and the conditions for knowledge sharing in terms of risk, trust and
control. The level of analysis is an interfirm relationship between competing firms.
Key concepts
For the purposes of this study, we first need to define what we mean by the key terms coopetition,
knowledge sharing and organizational learning. Coopetition, by definition, is simultaneous
competition and cooperation between firms. By cooperation we refer to an alliance or a business
relationship that is more than an arm’s length relationship (for a review on different alliance
structures, see e.g. Contractor and Lorange, 2002). In part, competition can be characterized in
Burt’s (1988, p. 358) words: “to the extent that producers of one commodity and the producers of
another have identical suppliers and identical consumers, they are competitors in the same
market.” By taking these definitions of cooperation and competition together, our conceptual
definition for coopetition in this paper can be laid down as a strategic cooperative relationship
between firms that are competitors in the same end product and strategic resource markets.
The above definition has some important implications for the context of our study. First, because
the relationship between the participants is strategically important, it is likely to include many
features such as relationship-specific assets and knowledge sharing practices or routines (Dyer
and Hatch, 2006; Dyer and Singh, 1998; Heiman and Nickerson, 2004), which enable effective
knowledge sharing. Second, because the participants in this relationship are actual competitors,
they can benefit from knowledge that they might obtain from the other party, and use it in their
own operations. Indeed, according to Dussauge et al. (2000) competing firms are likely to have
increased relative absorptive capacity (see e.g. Lane and Lubatkin, 1998), which makes
commercialization of the acquired knowledge fast and easier with respect to the situation where
cooperation occurs between non-competitors. Thus, both the benefits and risks are highlighted in
this kind of a relationship.
Knowledge has been identified as the most important asset for value creation (Grant, 1996).
Knowledge sharing provides the actual link between individuals and the level of the organization,
where knowledge and expertise attain their economic and competitive value. It is therefore
important to realize what knowledge is shared, with whom, and under which conditions. In
general, knowledge sharing presumes a two-way relation between at least two parties (i.e.
knowing subjects), of which one communicates knowledge either consciously or not, and the
other should be able to perceive knowledge expressions and make sense of them (Hendriks,
1999). Sharing is performed on a regular basis, via formal and informal channels, and even
spontaneously. Knowledge, as opposed to information, cannot be disseminated as such without
some shared practices or frames (Brown and Duguid, 2001).
As we have noted in the above definitions, knowledge carries a tacit, less transferable dimension;
hence, individuals are likely to be the key players in knowledge sharing processes also in
coopetitive relationships. Sharing is most inherent for inter-personal groups (such as project
teams, job groups, networks of expertise, design groups or communities of practice) which form
the actual context in which most knowledge processes are likely to take place. Such groups may
provide the link between the individual and organizational levels of knowledge sharing. (Soekijad
and Andriessen, 2003)
Organizational learning has been defined in numerous ways. One debate has been under the
question of “who learns”. The first answer is that the individuals in the organization learn and the
organization’s learning is the sum of its individuals’ learning experiences (e.g. Senge, 1990). The
second answer is that organizations themselves are capable of learning as social entities (e.g.
Walsh and Ungson, 1991). In this study, we adopt a view that organizations are capable of
learning in both ways, as the individuals’ sum of learning and as organizations themselves.
Similarity, proximity, quality, and the longetivity of the relationships, among others, affect how
organizations learn from knowledge being shared (Argote, 2000; Zollo et al., 2002).
Knowledge sharing and learning in coopetition
Accessing or acquiring the partner’s knowledge – technology, individual know-how, and
organizational capabilities – is often the primary objective and motivation for firms to form
alliances (Grant and Baden-Fuller, 2004; Ireland et al., 2002). Furthermore, it should be noted
that in the context of coopetition, firms tend to have increased absorptive capacity with respect to
each other. This is possible because they have, to some extent, a common knowledge base and
understanding because of their position in similar markets (Cohen and Levinthal, 1990; Dussauge
et al., 2000; Lane and Lubatkin, 1998). This means that they can quickly commercialize the
knowledge that they have acquired. Indeed, it has been noted that alliance members that are
competitors sometimes compete on who can learn more from the alliance (Hamel, 1991). With
regard to coopetition, this can lead to success or failure from the single firm’s viewpoint.
Sometimes alliances between competitors end up in transfer of knowledge and resources to the
other party (Dussauge et al., 2000), or failure (Park and Russo, 1996). Thus, firms have been
noted, for example, to restrict the scope of the alliance in order to manage threats of coopetition
(Oxley and Sampson, 2004). Hence, it is important to recognize that firms can have diverse
learning motives in alliances between competitors.
According to Argote (2000), learning from competitors significantly contributes to the focal
firm’s productivity, even if firms in general do not learn as much from their competitors as from
their own experience. In addition, von Krogh et al. (2001, 433) state that alliances with
competitors might provide new knowledge about their strategies, technologies and personnel
resources, thereby enhancing the internal capability to predict their future strategies. In general,
learning in alliances can be defined either competitive or cooperative. Some authors claim that
alliances are often formed in order to learn from them, and thus firms sometimes try to outlearn
their partners (e.g. Hamel, 1991; Ireland et al., 2002). On the other hand, some authors underline
the meaning of cooperative, reciprocal learning which is aimed at mutual knowledge creation and
development (Dyer and Hatch, 2006; Dyer and Singh, 1998; Lubatkin et al., 2001).
With respect to the discussion above, it is evident that coopetition entails risks of losing firm-
specific knowledge to a competitor. Thus, firms might create barriers to knowledge sharing
because of fear of opportunistic use of acquired knowledge. In such a context, it is fundamental
to create trust between the individuals and organizations (see e.g. Soekijad and Andriessen,
2003). Collaboration in an alliance between competitors can be accomplished when people
engage in social activities together and the situation involves affective trust. On the
organizational level, each organization in the alliance must be willing and able to share
knowledge (motivations to learn, transparency, and receptivity). The relationship through which
knowledge sharing takes place also provides an important set of facilitating conditions such as
trust, strength of ties, positive former experiences about co-operation in alliances, and a favorable
climate. (Soekijad and Andriessen, 2003; Panteli and Sockalingam, 2005)
In prior research, especially trust has been identified as a catalyst for knowledge sharing (eg.
Davenport and Prusak, 1998; Miles et al., 2000; Blomqvist, 2002). Based on the above
discussion, we note the importance of trust on both individual and organizational levels. Hence,
we now discuss the role of trust and the related issue of risk in more detail in the next chapter.
Trust, control and risk in knowledge sharing
According to Blau (1964), two factors initially account for the basis of trust: relationships have a
repetitive character, and achievements increase in importance in the course of time. In addition,
there has to be dependency on the other party, meaning that the interests of one party are
furthered only by reliance upon the other one (Mayer et al., 1995). This implies the importance of
trust for knowledge sharing in cooperative relationships. In economic terms, trust here means “a
particular level of the subjective probability with which an agent assesses that another agent or
group of agents will perform a particular action, both before he can monitor such action (or
independently of his capacity ever to be able to monitor it) and in a context in which it affects his
own action” (Gambetta, 1988, p. 217). Psychology, in turn, assesses trust in terms of internal
cognitions and affected by personal attributes, thus seeing trust as a general expectancy held by
an individual or a group that the other party involved can be relied upon (cf. Rotter, 1967).
Finally, many authors stress the social view on trust, being embedded in relationships among
people or institutions (Granovetter, 1985; Coleman, 1990; Mayer et al., 1995).
In business contexts, trust can be defined as “an actor’s expectation of the other party’s
competence and goodwill” (Blomqvist, 1997, p. 282). The definition implies the two underlying
dimensions of trust, competence (capabilities, skills and know-how) and goodwill, which
represents the more abstract bases (moral responsibility and positive intentions) of making trust
decisions. Accordingly, two types of trust can be identified: Calculus-based trust is based on a
rational choice and relies on credible information regarding the other party’s intentions and
competence, whereas relational trust derives from repeated interactions, and the relationship itself
forms the basis of making trust decisions (Rousseau et al., 1998). This type of trust is also
referred to as identity-based trust or affective trust (Coleman, 1990; McAllister, 1995).
Risk and trust exist simultaneously. Trust is not needed if there is complete certainty about the
results of actions: it is a solution to specific problems of risk (Coleman, 1990; Luhmann, 1988;
Lewis and Weigert, 1985). Risk suggests a future-oriented, unwelcome and threatening state of
the world; it is impossible to prevent, at least to some extent, and involves consequences that
result from human decisions. It is thus activated by our actions. Placing trust means suspending
the risk, acting as if it were non-existent (Luhmann, 1979; Sztompka, 1999). Trust also has its
counterpart, control. According to Mayer et al. (1995), control mechanisms may lead to
cooperation even if trust is absent, such as when sanctioning systems are in place to punish those
who default. In alliances, risks can be considered as relational risks (non-satisfactory
cooperation) and performance risks (alliance objectives are not achieved).
There are two separate but intertwined routes to reduce risk: trust and control, which determine
the total perceived risk in the alliance, yet neither of them can fully ensure a positive outcome
(Das and Teng, 1998, 2001). Control can be viewed as a process of regulation and monitoring in
order to achieve organizational goals; according to Leifer and Mills (1996, p. 117, ref. in Das and
Teng, 2001), control refers to “a regulatory process by which the elements of a system are made
more predictable through the establishment of standards in the pursuit of some desired objective
or state.” In alliances, three types of control have been identified: behavior control focuses on the
processes, output control is related to alliance performance, and social control involves the
establishment of common culture and values. Control can be achieved e.g. through governance
structures, contractual specifications and managerial arrangements. (Ibid.)
Generally, control comes into play in situations where adequate levels of trust are not present
(Rousseau et al., 1998). Thus it can be stated that when there are risks in the relationship, certain
proportions of trust or control are needed to facilitate knowledge sharing. For instance, two-sided
communication between individuals involved in a risky situation may be hindered when there is
no trust in others’ goodwill and competence. Furthermore, the existence of the norm of
reciprocity in knowledge sharing has relevance only in case one party is justified to believe that
the other will adapt to it (Castelfranchi and Tan, 2002), meaning that trust lubricates norm
enforcement. Consequently, without trust on the organizational level, knowledge sharing and
learning are decreased if a risk such as using knowledge to competitive purposes is perceived by
any party involved.
Some controversies from prior research on trust and risk in alliances should be highlighted at this
point. First, Das and Teng (2001) consider trust and control as mere substitutes; consequently,
they conclude that trust is not a necessary condition for successful cooperation in an alliance.
However, it should be noted that reciprocal learning is a deliberate and uncontrolled process,
which particularly calls for interpersonal and interorganizational trust as facilitating conditions.
Hence, we argue that the role of trust and control is significantly affected by the type of
knowledge being shared and learned.
Secondly, Das and Teng (2001, p. 254) consider control as “a more proactive approach” than
trust, leading to lower risks due to directly affecting the behavior of the partner and not passively
relying on a positive expectation. This, however, seems to be more an issue of approaching trust
from calculative and cognitive bases, than a question of trust itself. For instance, Lahno (2002)
notes that trust does not only have rational expectations grounded in given information, but about
how such information is evaluated. Hence, the expectations are more like a consequence of
trusting than having a cognitive state beforehand. Hence, trust inherently involves a two-way
affective relationship: knowing that one is being trusted affects both the motivations and behavior
of the trustee. (Lahno, 2002)
All in all, knowledge sharing in alliances requires a balance between trust and control, and
mutual understanding of the alliance member firms’ motivations and goals. The actual processes
of knowledge sharing also intertwine interpersonal and inter-organizational characteristics and
interactions. This is challenging in coopetitive relationships, because there is a need to
incorporate such processes into the strategic goals of the alliance. It is therefore fundamental to
understand what kind of knowledge is shared between alliance members, how sharing is affected
by and how it affects risk, trust, and control.
A framework of alliance-related knowledge in coopetition
So far, we have discussed the role of trust, control and risk with respect to knowledge sharing in
alliances. They are, however, strictly interconnected with the type of knowledge that is shared
and learned. Sometimes, competitors acquire knowledge from each other in order to outlearn
each other and maximize their own benefits. However, this is certainly not always the case. This
means that in order to understand the challenges that exist in the situation of knowledge sharing
between competitors in an alliance, the motives of learning in this kind of alliances should be
carefully assessed.
According to the earlier literature (Das and Kumar, 2007; Inkpen, 2000; Soekijad and Andriessen,
2003), the learning motivations of alliances can be classified in three broad categories. First,
firms can acquire knowledge straightly related to the alliance activities of a particular alliance;
second, firms can learn knowledge used to improve the design and management of other
alliances; and third, firms can acquire knowledge unrelated to alliance activities, and which they
can apply outside the alliance in their own operations.
For the purposes of this study, we formulate a distinction of three types of knowledge that are
related to the learning motives mentioned above. First, firms can acquire knowledge of how to
operate and create value in a specific alliance. We label this kind of knowledge alliance-specific,
which implies that it is useful in a given context with a given partner/partners. Consequently, we
call the second type of knowledge alliance-generic, which describes knowledge that can be
applied to alliances in general. Finally, we call the third type of knowledge alliance-external,
which describes knowledge that can be used for the benefit of a focal firm, external to the
alliance. Thus, we focus on three types of alliance-related knowledge, which all have distinct
differences in the context of coopetition. Figure 1 illustrates the framework of the types of
learning in alliances and the related challenges in coopetition.
Figure 1. Types of alliance-related knowledge
As Figure 1 shows, organizational learning can be divided into three distinct motivations that
differ in their nature with respect to the roles of risk, trust and control, and the level of
reciprocity. In the following sub-chapters, we discuss each of the motives more closely.
Organizational
learning
Alliance-specific
Alliance-generic
Alliance-external
Perceived risk:
low
-Goodwill trust
-Competence trust
Perceived risk:
low
-Social control
Perceived risk: high
-Behaviour control
-Output control
-Competence trust
Alliance-specific knowledge
Knowledge used to improve the operations of the on-going relationship is a motive that can be
considered as a prospect for the success of an alliance. Learning this type of knowledge can
consist of learning of both how individual and organizational aspects operate between alliance
members, and how they can be developed to create more value. When knowledge cumulates
about these kinds of operations, they can be called inter-organizational routines, which mainly
develop in the course of time (Zollo et al., 2002). This type of learning can also be reciprocal,
which can be more fruitful than one-sided learning (Lubatkin et al., 2001).
In a situation, where mutual learning accumulates over the course of an alliance, trust between
parties grows higher. In such a relationship, goodwill trust is often based on experiences about
the other party. In a similar vein, the perceived competencies of the alliance partner reduce the
perceived risk (Das and Teng, 2001). Learning by one party improves the results of another
because the learning that is alliance-specific will enhance overall alliance performance and
flexibility. In addition, this type of learning does not include risk of unintended knowledge spill-
over; on the contrary, knowledge sharing is preferred to boost mutual learning. Thus, there is an
opportunity to gain relational rents (Dyer and Singh, 1998), because parties trust each other and
are therefore more efficient in governing the whole relationship and creating knowledge sharing
routines.
Alliance-generic knowledge
Alliance-generic knowledge can be described a “neutral zone” as a subject of learning
motivation. This type of learning consists of both individual and organizational experiences,
practices, and skills of how to operate with another organization in order to pursue individual and
mutual goals. Alliance-generic knowledge could thus be understood as part of a larger meta-
capability to collaborate (Miles et al., 2000). Indeed, this type of knowledge is useful to a given
firm in the long run and helps it to outperform other firms that are not as good in alliance
management and practices (see e.g. Dyer and Hatch, 2006; Ritter et al., 2002). Learning this type
of knowledge cannot be harmful to another firm in a distinct alliance, and therefore this type of
learning does not create conflicts in a coopetitive relationship. Due to reduced levels of risk,
relatively low levels of trust and control are characteristic of this type of knowledge.
In the long run, alliance capability, i.e. the capability to learn in alliances in general, will relate
positively to alliance performance (Kale and Singh, 2007). Thus, firms will benefit from the
improved ability of their partners’ alliance capabilities in the long run, if the relationship
continues.
Alliance-external knowledge
From the perspective of coopetition, there is an evident risk that learning unrelated to alliance
activities takes place and is used in competitive operations (Bengtsson and Kock, 2000; Hamel,
1991). If this kind of learning is a motive for one party, it can be said that learning is asymmetric,
and one party might exit as a winner. If all the parties that are competitors focus on learning
alliance-external knowledge, the relationship might end up being a “learning race” (Hamel,
1991), which can deteriorate the benefits of the relationship, because parties become
overprotective of their knowledge. Indeed, there is evidence that firms in coopetitive
relationships narrow the scope and scale of the relationship in order to avoid risks (Oxley and
Sampson, 2004). Thus, if this kind of learning takes place – as it eventually does to some extent –
it is critical to balance between trust and control among parties if the functioning of the
relationship needs to be secured in the long run.
In the case of coopetition, it is evident that alliance-external knowledge can be used in
competitive operation against the alliance partner. Therefore it is extremely difficult to
accumulate trust between parties, and create opportunities for mutual value creation, if learning
of alliance-external knowledge takes place. There are basically two solutions in this situation:
decrease the scope and scale of alliance in order to prevent sharing knowledge from critical areas
(types of control) or accept the fact that some knowledge is transferred and utilized by a
competitor (calculative bases of trust, i.e. willingness to be vulnerable and carry the perceived
risk despite the lack of good intentions).
It must be noted that sometimes firms enter alliances in order to learn, and it is a desired outcome
which all parties agree on. If the possibility of learning alliance-external knowledge exists in
coopetition, a firm faces a strategic decision: if the benefits of the alliance outweigh the possible
negative consequences, it is rational to share knowledge even if the risk exists. This kind of
situation could be in the case where markets are just emerging and the possible benefits are very
high. For example, in the ICT sector competing firms cooperate intensively in the market creation
phase because of large network externalities (Fjelstad et al., 2004). Hence, we note that the bases
of making trust decisions are rational in nature.
Discussion and conclusions
Knowledge sharing and learning in alliances between competitors (i.e. coopetition) can be
challenging and risky, because knowledge can be used in either cooperation or competition.
However, there are many kinds of knowledge firms can learn from alliances, which all have
different implications for coopetition. For this reason, we formulated a typology of specific types
of alliance-related knowledge that are all subject to different learning motives.
First, alliance-specific knowledge is tied to the context of a distinct alliance, and thus this kind of
knowledge increases the possibility to create value in an alliance and is therefore beneficial for all
the parties. It is quite evident that when there are benefits to all the parties, knowledge sharing is
increased and a possibility of reciprocal learning exists. Second, alliance-generic knowledge can
be used in management of all alliances, and is therefore vital for the long-term competitiveness of
a single firm. Third, alliance-external knowledge gives a single firm an opportunity to improve its
own operations outside the alliance context. Learning this kind of knowledge creates a risk for
the other party in coopetition, if the knowledge is used opportunistically. Thus, trust and control
are both fundamentally important in order to enable the functioning of the alliance if this kind of
knowledge is present. In addition, it should be noted that alliance-external knowledge can also be
used for non-competitive purposes and thus increase the value a single firm acquires from the
alliance without hurting the counterpart.
Theoretically, our study makes an argument about the types of alliance-related knowledge and
their implications in coopetition, and alliances in general. Our main contribution to the existing
literature is the explicit recognition of each type of alliance-related knowledge by introducing the
three concepts of alliance-specific, alliance-generic and alliance-external knowledge, and
identifying the role of risk, trust and control with respect to them. We also highlight the
importance of intertwining the individual and organizational level issues on knowledge sharing
and learning in coopetitive alliances.
The managerial implications of our study draw attention to recognizing that alliance members
have different motivations and possibilities of benefiting from alliance-related knowledge.
Especially in coopetition, the knowledge shared and learned is in a major role when risks and
benefits of the relationship are assessed.
Our paper is theoretical in nature and thus only a first step in assessing how firms’ learning
motivations affect alliances between competitors. It should be useful, therefore, to examine
empirically how learning of different types of knowledge affect the knowledge sharing and
learning, management and structures of coopetitive relationships. Further research could also
incorporate discussion about how trust and control evolve over time in coopetitive relationships.
Finally, our theoretical ideas could be expanded onto the field to consider the different types of
alliances between competitors.
References
Argote, L. 2000. Organizational Learning. Creating, Retaining and Transferring Knowledge. Norwell,
MA: Kluwer Academic Publishers.
Bengtsson M. and Kock S. 2000. "Coopetition" in business networks - to cooperate and compete
simultaneously. Industrial Marketing Management, Vol. 29, No. 5, 411-426.
Blau, P. 1964. Exchange and Power in Social Life. New York: John Wiley & Sons.
Blomqvist, K. 1997. The Many Faces of Trust. Scandinavian Journal of Management, Vol. 13, No. 3, 271-
286.
Blomqvist, K. 2002. Partnering in the dynamic environment: The role of trust in asymmetric technology
partnership formation. Acta Universitatis Lappeenrantaensis, 122.
Brandenburger A.M. and Nalebuff B.J. 1995. The right game: Use game theory to shape strategy, Harvard
Business Review, Vol. 73, No. 4, 57-71.
Brandenburger A.M. and Nalebuff B.J. 1996. Co-opetition. Currency/Doubleday: New York.
Brown, J.S. and Duguid, P. 2001. Knowledge and Organization: A Social-Practice Perspective.
Organization Science, Vol 12, No. 2, pp.198-213.
Burt R. 1988. The stability of American markets. American Journal of Sosiology, Vol. 94, No, 356-395.
Castelfranchi, C. and Tan, Y. 2002. The role of trust and deception in virtual societies. International
Journal of Electronic Commerce, Vol. 6, No. 3, 55-70.
Cohen W.M. and Levinthal D.A. 1990. Absorptive capacity: A new perspective on learning and
innovation. Administrative Science Quarterly, Vol. 35, No. 1, 128-152.
Coleman, J. 1990. Foundations of Social Theory. Cambridge, MA: Belknap Press.
Contractor F.J. and Lorange P. 2002. The Growth of Alliances in the Knowledge-based Economy.
International Business Review, Vol. 11, No. 4, 485-502.
Das T.K. and Kumar R. 2007. Learning dynamics in the alliance development process, Management
Decicion, Vol. 45, No. 4, 684-707.
Das, T.K. and Teng, B. 1998. Between Trust and Control: Developing Confidence in Partner Cooperation
in Alliances. Academy of Management Review, Vol. 23, 491-512.
Das, T.K. and Teng, B. 2001. Trust, Control, and Risk in Strategic Alliances: An Integrated Framework.
Organization Studies, Vol. 22, No. 2, 251-283.
Davenport, T. and Prusak, L. 1998. Working Knowledge: How Organizations Manage What They Know.
Boston, MA: Harvard Business School Press.
Dussauge P., Garrette B. and Mitchell W. 2000. Learning from competing partners: Outcomes and
durations of scale and link alliances in Europe, North America and Asia. Strategic Management
Journal, Vol. 21, No. 2, 99-126.
Dyer J.H. and Hatch N.W. 2006. Relation-specific capabilities and barriers to knowledge transfers:
Creating advantage through network relationships. Strategic Management Journal, Vol. 27, No. 8,
701-719.
Dyer J.H. and Singh H. 1998. The relational view: Cooperative strategy and sources of interorganizational
competitive advantage. The Academy of Management Review, Vol. 23, No. 4, 660-679.
Fjelstad Ø.D., Becerra M. and Narayanan S. 2004. Strategic action in network industries: An empirical
analysis of the European mobile phone industry. Scandinavian Journal of Management, Vol. 20,
No, 173-196.
Gambetta, D. 1988. Trust: Making and Breaking Cooperative Relations. Oxford: Blackwell.
Granovetter, M. 1985. Economic action and social structure. American Journal of Sociology, Vol. 91, 481-
510.
Grant R.M. 1996. Toward a knowledge-based theory of the firm. Strategic Management Journal, Vol. 17,
Winter Special Issue, 109-122.
Grant R.M. and Baden-Fuller C. 2004. A knowledge accessing theory of strategic alliances. Journal of
Management Studies, Vol. 41, No. 1, 61-84.
Hamel G. 1991. Competition for competence and inter-partner learning within international strategic
alliances. Strategic Management Journal, Vol. 12, Summer special issue, 83-103.
Harbison J.R. and Pekar P.J. 1998. Smart Alliances. Jossey-Bass: San Fransisco.
Heiman B.A. and Nickerson J.A. 2004. Empirical evidence regarding the tension between knowledge
sharing and knowledge expropriation in collaborations. Managerial and Decision Economics, Vol.
26, No. 6-7, 401-420.
Hendriks, P. 1999. Why Share Knowledge? The Influence of ICT on the Motivation for Knowledge
Sharing. Knowledge and Process Management, Vol. 6, No. 2, 91-100.
Inkpen A.C. 2000. Learning through joint ventures: A framework of knowledge acquisition. Journal of
Management Studies, Vol. 37, No. 7, 1019-1043.
Ireland R.D., Hitt M.A. and Vaidyanath D. 2002 Alliance management as a source of competitive
advantage. Journal of Management, Vol. 28, No. 3, 413-446.
Kale P. and Singh H. 2007. Building firm capabilities through learning: The role of the alliance learning
process in alliance capability and firm-level alliance success. Strategic Management Journal, Vol.
28, No. 10, 981-1000.
Krogh von, G., Nonaka, I. & Aben, M. 2001. Making the Most of Your Company’s Knowledge: A
Strategic Framework. Long Range Planning, Vol. 34, No. 4, 421-439.
Lahno, B. 2002. Institutional Trust: A Less Demanding Form of Trust? Originally in Revista
Latinoamericana de Estudios Avanzados (RELEA), Caracas, 16.
Lane P.J. and Lubatkin M. 1998. Relative absorptive capacity and interorganizational learning. Strategic
Management Journal, Vol. 19, No. 5, 461-477.
Lewis, D. and Weigert, A. 1985. Trust as Social Reality. Social Forces, Vol. 63, No. 4, 967-985.
Loebbecke C., Fenema P.v. and Powell P. 1998. Knowledge transfer under coopetition. In Information
Systems: Current Issues and Future Changes, Larsen T, Levine L, DeGross J (eds).
Lubatkin M., Florin J. and Lane P.J. 2001. Learning together and apart: A model of reciprocal interfirm
learning. Human Relations, Vol. 54, No. 10, 1353-1382.
Luhmann, N. 1979. Trust and Power. Chichester: Wiley.
Luo X., Rindfleisch A. and Tse D.K. 2007. Working with rivals: The impact of competitor alliances in
financial performance. Journal of Marketing Research, Vol. 44, 73-83.
Mayer, R., Davis, J. and Schoorman, D. 1995. An integrative model of organizational trust. Academy of
Management Review, Vol. 20, No. 3, 709-734.
McAllister, D. 1995. Affect- and cognition-based trust as foundations for interpersonal cooperation in
organizations. Academy of Management Journal, Vol. 38, No. 1, 24-59.
McGill J.P. 2007. Technological knowledge and governance in alliances among competitors. International
Journal of Technology Management, Vol. 38, No. 1/2, 69-89.
Miles R.E., Snow C.C. and Miles G. 2000. TheFuture.org. Long Range Planning, Vol. 33, No. 3, 300-321.
Oxley J.E. and Sampson R.C. 2004. The scope and governance of international R&D alliances. Strategic
Management Journal, Vol. 25, No. 8-9, 723-749.
Park S.H. and Russo M.V. 1996. ‘When competition eclipses cooperation: An event history analysis of
joint venture failure’, Management Science, Vol. 42, No. 6, 875-890.
Panteli, N. and Sockalingam, S. 2005. Trust and conflict within virtual inter-organizational alliances: a
framework for facilitating knowledge sharing. Decision Support Systems, Vol. 39, 599-617.
Quintana-GarcĂ­a C. and Benavides-Velasco C.A. 2004. Cooperation, competition, and innovative
capability: A panel data of European dedicated biotechnology firms. Technovation, Vol. 24, No.
12, 927-938.
Ritter T., Wilkinson I.F. and Johnston W.J. 2002. Measuring network competence: Some international
evidence. Journal of Business and Industrial Marketing, Vol. 17, No. 2/3, 119-138.
Rotter, J. 1967. A new scale for the measurement of interpersonal trust. Journal of Personality, Vol. 35,
615-665.
Rousseau, D., Sitkin, S., Burt, R. and Camerer, C. 1998. Not so different at all: A cross-discipline view of
trust. Academy of Management Review, Vol. 23, No. 3, 393-404.
Senge P.M. 1990. The Fifth Discipline - The Art and Practice of the Learning Organization. Doubleday:
New York.
Soekijad M. and Andriessen E. 2003. Conditions for knowledge sharing in competitive alliances.
European Management Journal, Vol. 21, No. 5, 578-587.
Sztompka, D. 1999. Trust: A Sociological Theory. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Walsh J.P. and Ungson G.R. 1991. Organizational memory. The Academy of Management Review, Vol.
16, No. 1, 57-91.
Zollo M., Reuer J.J. and Singh H. 2002. Interorganizational routines and performance in strategic
alliances. Organization Science, Vol. 13, No. 6, 701-713.

More Related Content

What's hot

A Study On The Relationship Between Corporate Reputation And Customer Loyalty...
A Study On The Relationship Between Corporate Reputation And Customer Loyalty...A Study On The Relationship Between Corporate Reputation And Customer Loyalty...
A Study On The Relationship Between Corporate Reputation And Customer Loyalty...inventionjournals
 
Allfresh 2012 lin
Allfresh 2012 linAllfresh 2012 lin
Allfresh 2012 linDanie Schoeman
 
FACTORS AFFECTING THE COLLABORATION IN SUPPLY CHAIN OF MECHANICAL ENTERPRISES...
FACTORS AFFECTING THE COLLABORATION IN SUPPLY CHAIN OF MECHANICAL ENTERPRISES...FACTORS AFFECTING THE COLLABORATION IN SUPPLY CHAIN OF MECHANICAL ENTERPRISES...
FACTORS AFFECTING THE COLLABORATION IN SUPPLY CHAIN OF MECHANICAL ENTERPRISES...ijmvsc
 
Achieving sustainable competitive advantage through resource configur
Achieving sustainable competitive advantage through resource configurAchieving sustainable competitive advantage through resource configur
Achieving sustainable competitive advantage through resource configurIAEME Publication
 
Communication of csr programs of MNc's an indian perspective
Communication of csr programs of MNc's an indian perspectiveCommunication of csr programs of MNc's an indian perspective
Communication of csr programs of MNc's an indian perspectiveTapasya123
 
A comparison of a competitive and non competitive outdoor
A comparison of a competitive and non competitive outdoor A comparison of a competitive and non competitive outdoor
A comparison of a competitive and non competitive outdoor Kristian Suhartadi
 
Communication of CSR Programs of MNCs:An Indian Perspective
Communication of CSR Programs of MNCs:An Indian PerspectiveCommunication of CSR Programs of MNCs:An Indian Perspective
Communication of CSR Programs of MNCs:An Indian Perspectiveprofessionalpanorama
 
Pdf lander kooning
Pdf lander kooningPdf lander kooning
Pdf lander kooningBURESI
 
S 9735-pe
S 9735-peS 9735-pe
S 9735-peSamir Sami
 
15707 53009-1-pb (1)
15707 53009-1-pb (1)15707 53009-1-pb (1)
15707 53009-1-pb (1)Samir Sami
 

What's hot (11)

A Study On The Relationship Between Corporate Reputation And Customer Loyalty...
A Study On The Relationship Between Corporate Reputation And Customer Loyalty...A Study On The Relationship Between Corporate Reputation And Customer Loyalty...
A Study On The Relationship Between Corporate Reputation And Customer Loyalty...
 
Allfresh 2012 lin
Allfresh 2012 linAllfresh 2012 lin
Allfresh 2012 lin
 
FACTORS AFFECTING THE COLLABORATION IN SUPPLY CHAIN OF MECHANICAL ENTERPRISES...
FACTORS AFFECTING THE COLLABORATION IN SUPPLY CHAIN OF MECHANICAL ENTERPRISES...FACTORS AFFECTING THE COLLABORATION IN SUPPLY CHAIN OF MECHANICAL ENTERPRISES...
FACTORS AFFECTING THE COLLABORATION IN SUPPLY CHAIN OF MECHANICAL ENTERPRISES...
 
Achieving sustainable competitive advantage through resource configur
Achieving sustainable competitive advantage through resource configurAchieving sustainable competitive advantage through resource configur
Achieving sustainable competitive advantage through resource configur
 
Communication of csr programs of MNc's an indian perspective
Communication of csr programs of MNc's an indian perspectiveCommunication of csr programs of MNc's an indian perspective
Communication of csr programs of MNc's an indian perspective
 
A comparison of a competitive and non competitive outdoor
A comparison of a competitive and non competitive outdoor A comparison of a competitive and non competitive outdoor
A comparison of a competitive and non competitive outdoor
 
Communication of CSR Programs of MNCs:An Indian Perspective
Communication of CSR Programs of MNCs:An Indian PerspectiveCommunication of CSR Programs of MNCs:An Indian Perspective
Communication of CSR Programs of MNCs:An Indian Perspective
 
Pdf lander kooning
Pdf lander kooningPdf lander kooning
Pdf lander kooning
 
S 9735-pe
S 9735-peS 9735-pe
S 9735-pe
 
15707 53009-1-pb (1)
15707 53009-1-pb (1)15707 53009-1-pb (1)
15707 53009-1-pb (1)
 
Knowledge Management solutions, mechanisms and infrastructure
Knowledge Management solutions, mechanisms and infrastructureKnowledge Management solutions, mechanisms and infrastructure
Knowledge Management solutions, mechanisms and infrastructure
 

Viewers also liked

Bases militares eeuu en colombia otero prada (1)
Bases militares eeuu en colombia   otero prada (1)Bases militares eeuu en colombia   otero prada (1)
Bases militares eeuu en colombia otero prada (1)Mariluz Salinas
 
Castellano trabajo final
Castellano trabajo finalCastellano trabajo final
Castellano trabajo finaljmanero1999
 
REST+JS - Codebits 2011
REST+JS - Codebits 2011REST+JS - Codebits 2011
REST+JS - Codebits 2011JoĂŁo Nelas
 
Ley pesca extremadura 2011
Ley pesca extremadura 2011Ley pesca extremadura 2011
Ley pesca extremadura 2011muchapesca
 
Valle romano kutxa
Valle romano kutxaValle romano kutxa
Valle romano kutxaguest7439ecf
 
RANCHO DE GANGA
RANCHO DE GANGARANCHO DE GANGA
RANCHO DE GANGAmoranjaime
 
20151105_Infoday RS1_Juan Riese
20151105_Infoday RS1_Juan Riese20151105_Infoday RS1_Juan Riese
20151105_Infoday RS1_Juan RieseRedit
 
SI TU CORAZÓN TE FALLA
SI TU CORAZÓN TE FALLASI TU CORAZÓN TE FALLA
SI TU CORAZÓN TE FALLA19JESUS52
 
Realismo Magico En La Literatura De Moni K
Realismo Magico En La Literatura De Moni KRealismo Magico En La Literatura De Moni K
Realismo Magico En La Literatura De Moni Kmonica andrea
 
Diseño del controlador de robot móvil en el proceso de soldadura de la constr...
Diseño del controlador de robot móvil en el proceso de soldadura de la constr...Diseño del controlador de robot móvil en el proceso de soldadura de la constr...
Diseño del controlador de robot móvil en el proceso de soldadura de la constr...jhonatan lino echavarria
 
China antimony industry report, 2010
China antimony industry report, 2010China antimony industry report, 2010
China antimony industry report, 2010ResearchInChina
 
Los secrfetos de la excelencia
Los secrfetos de la excelenciaLos secrfetos de la excelencia
Los secrfetos de la excelenciamerchandisingservice
 
Pueblos con encanto
Pueblos con encantoPueblos con encanto
Pueblos con encantoJuan Ignacio B.
 
Virgo 3.0, OSGi middleware server from EclipseRT – Christopher Frost
Virgo 3.0, OSGi middleware server from EclipseRT – Christopher FrostVirgo 3.0, OSGi middleware server from EclipseRT – Christopher Frost
Virgo 3.0, OSGi middleware server from EclipseRT – Christopher Frostmfrancis
 
TP2 PROCOM ROTARY INTERNATIONAL
TP2 PROCOM ROTARY INTERNATIONALTP2 PROCOM ROTARY INTERNATIONAL
TP2 PROCOM ROTARY INTERNATIONALmafe07
 

Viewers also liked (20)

Bases militares eeuu en colombia otero prada (1)
Bases militares eeuu en colombia   otero prada (1)Bases militares eeuu en colombia   otero prada (1)
Bases militares eeuu en colombia otero prada (1)
 
Castellano trabajo final
Castellano trabajo finalCastellano trabajo final
Castellano trabajo final
 
Viento a Favor
Viento a FavorViento a Favor
Viento a Favor
 
Saga la guarida del escriba
Saga la guarida del escribaSaga la guarida del escriba
Saga la guarida del escriba
 
Mappe 5 B 2012 2013
Mappe 5 B 2012 2013Mappe 5 B 2012 2013
Mappe 5 B 2012 2013
 
REST+JS - Codebits 2011
REST+JS - Codebits 2011REST+JS - Codebits 2011
REST+JS - Codebits 2011
 
Ley pesca extremadura 2011
Ley pesca extremadura 2011Ley pesca extremadura 2011
Ley pesca extremadura 2011
 
Verbatim Gateway Alarm Autodialer Training
Verbatim Gateway Alarm Autodialer TrainingVerbatim Gateway Alarm Autodialer Training
Verbatim Gateway Alarm Autodialer Training
 
Valle romano kutxa
Valle romano kutxaValle romano kutxa
Valle romano kutxa
 
RANCHO DE GANGA
RANCHO DE GANGARANCHO DE GANGA
RANCHO DE GANGA
 
20151105_Infoday RS1_Juan Riese
20151105_Infoday RS1_Juan Riese20151105_Infoday RS1_Juan Riese
20151105_Infoday RS1_Juan Riese
 
SI TU CORAZÓN TE FALLA
SI TU CORAZÓN TE FALLASI TU CORAZÓN TE FALLA
SI TU CORAZÓN TE FALLA
 
Realismo Magico En La Literatura De Moni K
Realismo Magico En La Literatura De Moni KRealismo Magico En La Literatura De Moni K
Realismo Magico En La Literatura De Moni K
 
Diseño del controlador de robot móvil en el proceso de soldadura de la constr...
Diseño del controlador de robot móvil en el proceso de soldadura de la constr...Diseño del controlador de robot móvil en el proceso de soldadura de la constr...
Diseño del controlador de robot móvil en el proceso de soldadura de la constr...
 
China antimony industry report, 2010
China antimony industry report, 2010China antimony industry report, 2010
China antimony industry report, 2010
 
Nuestra Feliz Infancia
Nuestra Feliz InfanciaNuestra Feliz Infancia
Nuestra Feliz Infancia
 
Los secrfetos de la excelencia
Los secrfetos de la excelenciaLos secrfetos de la excelencia
Los secrfetos de la excelencia
 
Pueblos con encanto
Pueblos con encantoPueblos con encanto
Pueblos con encanto
 
Virgo 3.0, OSGi middleware server from EclipseRT – Christopher Frost
Virgo 3.0, OSGi middleware server from EclipseRT – Christopher FrostVirgo 3.0, OSGi middleware server from EclipseRT – Christopher Frost
Virgo 3.0, OSGi middleware server from EclipseRT – Christopher Frost
 
TP2 PROCOM ROTARY INTERNATIONAL
TP2 PROCOM ROTARY INTERNATIONALTP2 PROCOM ROTARY INTERNATIONAL
TP2 PROCOM ROTARY INTERNATIONAL
 

Similar to Knowledge sharing in coopetitive alliances

A knowledge accessing theory of strategic alliance pdf1
A knowledge accessing theory of strategic      alliance pdf1A knowledge accessing theory of strategic      alliance pdf1
A knowledge accessing theory of strategic alliance pdf1Rose Kiprop
 
Golonka
GolonkaGolonka
GolonkaMateusz
 
High Performing Teams Research Paper
High Performing Teams Research PaperHigh Performing Teams Research Paper
High Performing Teams Research PaperTanya Williams
 
Leveraging strategies networks
Leveraging strategies networksLeveraging strategies networks
Leveraging strategies networksJuliet John
 
Learning in Interorganizational Relationships of the Union of Clothing Manufa...
Learning in Interorganizational Relationships of the Union of Clothing Manufa...Learning in Interorganizational Relationships of the Union of Clothing Manufa...
Learning in Interorganizational Relationships of the Union of Clothing Manufa...IJERA Editor
 
Knowledge management in universities in uganda a social perspective
Knowledge management in universities in uganda a social perspectiveKnowledge management in universities in uganda a social perspective
Knowledge management in universities in uganda a social perspectiveAlexander Decker
 
Seminarku123456789
Seminarku123456789Seminarku123456789
Seminarku123456789guest3aed2bc
 
F393139
F393139F393139
F393139aijbm
 
A stakeholder theory of the firm
A stakeholder theory of the firmA stakeholder theory of the firm
A stakeholder theory of the firmMateus Cozer
 
Assignment Social Media Strategy for Competitive Advantage .docx
Assignment Social Media Strategy for Competitive Advantage .docxAssignment Social Media Strategy for Competitive Advantage .docx
Assignment Social Media Strategy for Competitive Advantage .docxrock73
 
22 cross bordner-knowledge-transfer
22 cross bordner-knowledge-transfer22 cross bordner-knowledge-transfer
22 cross bordner-knowledge-transferLTGnetrade
 
Business innovation through knowledge sharing an applied study on the jordani...
Business innovation through knowledge sharing an applied study on the jordani...Business innovation through knowledge sharing an applied study on the jordani...
Business innovation through knowledge sharing an applied study on the jordani...Alexander Decker
 
An Analytical Study on Knowledge Sharing within the Organization
An Analytical Study on Knowledge Sharing within the OrganizationAn Analytical Study on Knowledge Sharing within the Organization
An Analytical Study on Knowledge Sharing within the Organizationijcnes
 
httpsdoi.org10.11772329488415613340International Jour
httpsdoi.org10.11772329488415613340International Jourhttpsdoi.org10.11772329488415613340International Jour
httpsdoi.org10.11772329488415613340International JourPazSilviapm
 
Summary Master_thesis
Summary Master_thesisSummary Master_thesis
Summary Master_thesisMaxime Georgin
 
Km model explanation
Km model explanationKm model explanation
Km model explanationAkshit Kumar
 
Running head GLOBALIZATION AND KNOWLEDGE MANAGEMENT  .docx
Running head GLOBALIZATION AND KNOWLEDGE MANAGEMENT           .docxRunning head GLOBALIZATION AND KNOWLEDGE MANAGEMENT           .docx
Running head GLOBALIZATION AND KNOWLEDGE MANAGEMENT  .docxcowinhelen
 
R&D collaborations and innovation performance the case of argentinean biotech...
R&D collaborations and innovation performance the case of argentinean biotech...R&D collaborations and innovation performance the case of argentinean biotech...
R&D collaborations and innovation performance the case of argentinean biotech...iBoP Asia
 

Similar to Knowledge sharing in coopetitive alliances (20)

A knowledge accessing theory of strategic alliance pdf1
A knowledge accessing theory of strategic      alliance pdf1A knowledge accessing theory of strategic      alliance pdf1
A knowledge accessing theory of strategic alliance pdf1
 
Golonka
GolonkaGolonka
Golonka
 
Social interaction 17
Social interaction 17Social interaction 17
Social interaction 17
 
High Performing Teams Research Paper
High Performing Teams Research PaperHigh Performing Teams Research Paper
High Performing Teams Research Paper
 
Leveraging strategies networks
Leveraging strategies networksLeveraging strategies networks
Leveraging strategies networks
 
Learning in Interorganizational Relationships of the Union of Clothing Manufa...
Learning in Interorganizational Relationships of the Union of Clothing Manufa...Learning in Interorganizational Relationships of the Union of Clothing Manufa...
Learning in Interorganizational Relationships of the Union of Clothing Manufa...
 
Knowledge management in universities in uganda a social perspective
Knowledge management in universities in uganda a social perspectiveKnowledge management in universities in uganda a social perspective
Knowledge management in universities in uganda a social perspective
 
Seminarku
SeminarkuSeminarku
Seminarku
 
Seminarku123456789
Seminarku123456789Seminarku123456789
Seminarku123456789
 
F393139
F393139F393139
F393139
 
A stakeholder theory of the firm
A stakeholder theory of the firmA stakeholder theory of the firm
A stakeholder theory of the firm
 
Assignment Social Media Strategy for Competitive Advantage .docx
Assignment Social Media Strategy for Competitive Advantage .docxAssignment Social Media Strategy for Competitive Advantage .docx
Assignment Social Media Strategy for Competitive Advantage .docx
 
22 cross bordner-knowledge-transfer
22 cross bordner-knowledge-transfer22 cross bordner-knowledge-transfer
22 cross bordner-knowledge-transfer
 
Business innovation through knowledge sharing an applied study on the jordani...
Business innovation through knowledge sharing an applied study on the jordani...Business innovation through knowledge sharing an applied study on the jordani...
Business innovation through knowledge sharing an applied study on the jordani...
 
An Analytical Study on Knowledge Sharing within the Organization
An Analytical Study on Knowledge Sharing within the OrganizationAn Analytical Study on Knowledge Sharing within the Organization
An Analytical Study on Knowledge Sharing within the Organization
 
httpsdoi.org10.11772329488415613340International Jour
httpsdoi.org10.11772329488415613340International Jourhttpsdoi.org10.11772329488415613340International Jour
httpsdoi.org10.11772329488415613340International Jour
 
Summary Master_thesis
Summary Master_thesisSummary Master_thesis
Summary Master_thesis
 
Km model explanation
Km model explanationKm model explanation
Km model explanation
 
Running head GLOBALIZATION AND KNOWLEDGE MANAGEMENT  .docx
Running head GLOBALIZATION AND KNOWLEDGE MANAGEMENT           .docxRunning head GLOBALIZATION AND KNOWLEDGE MANAGEMENT           .docx
Running head GLOBALIZATION AND KNOWLEDGE MANAGEMENT  .docx
 
R&D collaborations and innovation performance the case of argentinean biotech...
R&D collaborations and innovation performance the case of argentinean biotech...R&D collaborations and innovation performance the case of argentinean biotech...
R&D collaborations and innovation performance the case of argentinean biotech...
 

More from Miia Kosonen

Vastuullisempaa-somea
Vastuullisempaa-someaVastuullisempaa-somea
Vastuullisempaa-someaMiia Kosonen
 
Yhteisollisyys cmadfi-2022
Yhteisollisyys cmadfi-2022Yhteisollisyys cmadfi-2022
Yhteisollisyys cmadfi-2022Miia Kosonen
 
Sinulle sopiva somestrategia
Sinulle sopiva somestrategiaSinulle sopiva somestrategia
Sinulle sopiva somestrategiaMiia Kosonen
 
Itsensajohtaminen muutostilanteissa
Itsensajohtaminen muutostilanteissaItsensajohtaminen muutostilanteissa
Itsensajohtaminen muutostilanteissaMiia Kosonen
 
Tietojohtamisen tutkimus
Tietojohtamisen tutkimusTietojohtamisen tutkimus
Tietojohtamisen tutkimusMiia Kosonen
 
Twitter-likes
Twitter-likesTwitter-likes
Twitter-likesMiia Kosonen
 
Virtuaaliverkostot
VirtuaaliverkostotVirtuaaliverkostot
VirtuaaliverkostotMiia Kosonen
 
Yhteisollisyys
YhteisollisyysYhteisollisyys
YhteisollisyysMiia Kosonen
 
Sometutkimus
SometutkimusSometutkimus
SometutkimusMiia Kosonen
 
Tohtoriverkosto
TohtoriverkostoTohtoriverkosto
TohtoriverkostoMiia Kosonen
 
Eettisyys sosiaalisen median tutkimuskÀytössÀ
Eettisyys sosiaalisen median tutkimuskÀytössÀEettisyys sosiaalisen median tutkimuskÀytössÀ
Eettisyys sosiaalisen median tutkimuskÀytössÀMiia Kosonen
 
Keskustelu ja kuuntelu sosiaalisessa mediassa
Keskustelu ja kuuntelu sosiaalisessa mediassaKeskustelu ja kuuntelu sosiaalisessa mediassa
Keskustelu ja kuuntelu sosiaalisessa mediassaMiia Kosonen
 
Some ja oppimisverkostot
Some ja oppimisverkostotSome ja oppimisverkostot
Some ja oppimisverkostotMiia Kosonen
 
Tiedolla johtamisen illuusio
Tiedolla johtamisen illuusioTiedolla johtamisen illuusio
Tiedolla johtamisen illuusioMiia Kosonen
 
Digitaalisuus ja hiljainen tieto
Digitaalisuus ja hiljainen tietoDigitaalisuus ja hiljainen tieto
Digitaalisuus ja hiljainen tietoMiia Kosonen
 
Tietojohtaminen ja tiedolla johtaminen
Tietojohtaminen ja tiedolla johtaminenTietojohtaminen ja tiedolla johtaminen
Tietojohtaminen ja tiedolla johtaminenMiia Kosonen
 
Yhteisot ja tieto
Yhteisot ja tietoYhteisot ja tieto
Yhteisot ja tietoMiia Kosonen
 
Online community death
Online community deathOnline community death
Online community deathMiia Kosonen
 
Yhteisojen saattohoito
Yhteisojen saattohoitoYhteisojen saattohoito
Yhteisojen saattohoitoMiia Kosonen
 

More from Miia Kosonen (20)

Vastuullisempaa-somea
Vastuullisempaa-someaVastuullisempaa-somea
Vastuullisempaa-somea
 
Yhteisollisyys cmadfi-2022
Yhteisollisyys cmadfi-2022Yhteisollisyys cmadfi-2022
Yhteisollisyys cmadfi-2022
 
Sinulle sopiva somestrategia
Sinulle sopiva somestrategiaSinulle sopiva somestrategia
Sinulle sopiva somestrategia
 
Itsensajohtaminen muutostilanteissa
Itsensajohtaminen muutostilanteissaItsensajohtaminen muutostilanteissa
Itsensajohtaminen muutostilanteissa
 
Tietojohtamisen tutkimus
Tietojohtamisen tutkimusTietojohtamisen tutkimus
Tietojohtamisen tutkimus
 
Twitter-likes
Twitter-likesTwitter-likes
Twitter-likes
 
Virtuaaliverkostot
VirtuaaliverkostotVirtuaaliverkostot
Virtuaaliverkostot
 
Yhteisollisyys
YhteisollisyysYhteisollisyys
Yhteisollisyys
 
Sometutkimus
SometutkimusSometutkimus
Sometutkimus
 
Hinnoittelu
HinnoitteluHinnoittelu
Hinnoittelu
 
Tohtoriverkosto
TohtoriverkostoTohtoriverkosto
Tohtoriverkosto
 
Eettisyys sosiaalisen median tutkimuskÀytössÀ
Eettisyys sosiaalisen median tutkimuskÀytössÀEettisyys sosiaalisen median tutkimuskÀytössÀ
Eettisyys sosiaalisen median tutkimuskÀytössÀ
 
Keskustelu ja kuuntelu sosiaalisessa mediassa
Keskustelu ja kuuntelu sosiaalisessa mediassaKeskustelu ja kuuntelu sosiaalisessa mediassa
Keskustelu ja kuuntelu sosiaalisessa mediassa
 
Some ja oppimisverkostot
Some ja oppimisverkostotSome ja oppimisverkostot
Some ja oppimisverkostot
 
Tiedolla johtamisen illuusio
Tiedolla johtamisen illuusioTiedolla johtamisen illuusio
Tiedolla johtamisen illuusio
 
Digitaalisuus ja hiljainen tieto
Digitaalisuus ja hiljainen tietoDigitaalisuus ja hiljainen tieto
Digitaalisuus ja hiljainen tieto
 
Tietojohtaminen ja tiedolla johtaminen
Tietojohtaminen ja tiedolla johtaminenTietojohtaminen ja tiedolla johtaminen
Tietojohtaminen ja tiedolla johtaminen
 
Yhteisot ja tieto
Yhteisot ja tietoYhteisot ja tieto
Yhteisot ja tieto
 
Online community death
Online community deathOnline community death
Online community death
 
Yhteisojen saattohoito
Yhteisojen saattohoitoYhteisojen saattohoito
Yhteisojen saattohoito
 

Recently uploaded

MULTIDISCIPLINRY NATURE OF THE ENVIRONMENTAL STUDIES.pptx
MULTIDISCIPLINRY NATURE OF THE ENVIRONMENTAL STUDIES.pptxMULTIDISCIPLINRY NATURE OF THE ENVIRONMENTAL STUDIES.pptx
MULTIDISCIPLINRY NATURE OF THE ENVIRONMENTAL STUDIES.pptxAnupkumar Sharma
 
Earth Day Presentation wow hello nice great
Earth Day Presentation wow hello nice greatEarth Day Presentation wow hello nice great
Earth Day Presentation wow hello nice greatYousafMalik24
 
Planning a health career 4th Quarter.pptx
Planning a health career 4th Quarter.pptxPlanning a health career 4th Quarter.pptx
Planning a health career 4th Quarter.pptxLigayaBacuel1
 
Field Attribute Index Feature in Odoo 17
Field Attribute Index Feature in Odoo 17Field Attribute Index Feature in Odoo 17
Field Attribute Index Feature in Odoo 17Celine George
 
AMERICAN LANGUAGE HUB_Level2_Student'sBook_Answerkey.pdf
AMERICAN LANGUAGE HUB_Level2_Student'sBook_Answerkey.pdfAMERICAN LANGUAGE HUB_Level2_Student'sBook_Answerkey.pdf
AMERICAN LANGUAGE HUB_Level2_Student'sBook_Answerkey.pdfphamnguyenenglishnb
 
Introduction to AI in Higher Education_draft.pptx
Introduction to AI in Higher Education_draft.pptxIntroduction to AI in Higher Education_draft.pptx
Introduction to AI in Higher Education_draft.pptxpboyjonauth
 
ENGLISH 7_Q4_LESSON 2_ Employing a Variety of Strategies for Effective Interp...
ENGLISH 7_Q4_LESSON 2_ Employing a Variety of Strategies for Effective Interp...ENGLISH 7_Q4_LESSON 2_ Employing a Variety of Strategies for Effective Interp...
ENGLISH 7_Q4_LESSON 2_ Employing a Variety of Strategies for Effective Interp...JhezDiaz1
 
ECONOMIC CONTEXT - PAPER 1 Q3: NEWSPAPERS.pptx
ECONOMIC CONTEXT - PAPER 1 Q3: NEWSPAPERS.pptxECONOMIC CONTEXT - PAPER 1 Q3: NEWSPAPERS.pptx
ECONOMIC CONTEXT - PAPER 1 Q3: NEWSPAPERS.pptxiammrhaywood
 
Introduction to ArtificiaI Intelligence in Higher Education
Introduction to ArtificiaI Intelligence in Higher EducationIntroduction to ArtificiaI Intelligence in Higher Education
Introduction to ArtificiaI Intelligence in Higher Educationpboyjonauth
 
Grade 9 Q4-MELC1-Active and Passive Voice.pptx
Grade 9 Q4-MELC1-Active and Passive Voice.pptxGrade 9 Q4-MELC1-Active and Passive Voice.pptx
Grade 9 Q4-MELC1-Active and Passive Voice.pptxChelloAnnAsuncion2
 
HỌC TỐT TIáșŸNG ANH 11 THEO CHÆŻÆ NG TRÌNH GLOBAL SUCCESS ĐÁP ÁN CHI TIáșŸT - Cáșą NĂ...
HỌC TỐT TIáșŸNG ANH 11 THEO CHÆŻÆ NG TRÌNH GLOBAL SUCCESS ĐÁP ÁN CHI TIáșŸT - Cáșą NĂ...HỌC TỐT TIáșŸNG ANH 11 THEO CHÆŻÆ NG TRÌNH GLOBAL SUCCESS ĐÁP ÁN CHI TIáșŸT - Cáșą NĂ...
HỌC TỐT TIáșŸNG ANH 11 THEO CHÆŻÆ NG TRÌNH GLOBAL SUCCESS ĐÁP ÁN CHI TIáșŸT - Cáșą NĂ...Nguyen Thanh Tu Collection
 
ROOT CAUSE ANALYSIS PowerPoint Presentation
ROOT CAUSE ANALYSIS PowerPoint PresentationROOT CAUSE ANALYSIS PowerPoint Presentation
ROOT CAUSE ANALYSIS PowerPoint PresentationAadityaSharma884161
 
Employee wellbeing at the workplace.pptx
Employee wellbeing at the workplace.pptxEmployee wellbeing at the workplace.pptx
Employee wellbeing at the workplace.pptxNirmalaLoungPoorunde1
 
Judging the Relevance and worth of ideas part 2.pptx
Judging the Relevance  and worth of ideas part 2.pptxJudging the Relevance  and worth of ideas part 2.pptx
Judging the Relevance and worth of ideas part 2.pptxSherlyMaeNeri
 
DATA STRUCTURE AND ALGORITHM for beginners
DATA STRUCTURE AND ALGORITHM for beginnersDATA STRUCTURE AND ALGORITHM for beginners
DATA STRUCTURE AND ALGORITHM for beginnersSabitha Banu
 
How to do quick user assign in kanban in Odoo 17 ERP
How to do quick user assign in kanban in Odoo 17 ERPHow to do quick user assign in kanban in Odoo 17 ERP
How to do quick user assign in kanban in Odoo 17 ERPCeline George
 

Recently uploaded (20)

MULTIDISCIPLINRY NATURE OF THE ENVIRONMENTAL STUDIES.pptx
MULTIDISCIPLINRY NATURE OF THE ENVIRONMENTAL STUDIES.pptxMULTIDISCIPLINRY NATURE OF THE ENVIRONMENTAL STUDIES.pptx
MULTIDISCIPLINRY NATURE OF THE ENVIRONMENTAL STUDIES.pptx
 
OS-operating systems- ch04 (Threads) ...
OS-operating systems- ch04 (Threads) ...OS-operating systems- ch04 (Threads) ...
OS-operating systems- ch04 (Threads) ...
 
Earth Day Presentation wow hello nice great
Earth Day Presentation wow hello nice greatEarth Day Presentation wow hello nice great
Earth Day Presentation wow hello nice great
 
Planning a health career 4th Quarter.pptx
Planning a health career 4th Quarter.pptxPlanning a health career 4th Quarter.pptx
Planning a health career 4th Quarter.pptx
 
Model Call Girl in Bikash Puri Delhi reach out to us at 🔝9953056974🔝
Model Call Girl in Bikash Puri  Delhi reach out to us at 🔝9953056974🔝Model Call Girl in Bikash Puri  Delhi reach out to us at 🔝9953056974🔝
Model Call Girl in Bikash Puri Delhi reach out to us at 🔝9953056974🔝
 
Field Attribute Index Feature in Odoo 17
Field Attribute Index Feature in Odoo 17Field Attribute Index Feature in Odoo 17
Field Attribute Index Feature in Odoo 17
 
AMERICAN LANGUAGE HUB_Level2_Student'sBook_Answerkey.pdf
AMERICAN LANGUAGE HUB_Level2_Student'sBook_Answerkey.pdfAMERICAN LANGUAGE HUB_Level2_Student'sBook_Answerkey.pdf
AMERICAN LANGUAGE HUB_Level2_Student'sBook_Answerkey.pdf
 
Introduction to AI in Higher Education_draft.pptx
Introduction to AI in Higher Education_draft.pptxIntroduction to AI in Higher Education_draft.pptx
Introduction to AI in Higher Education_draft.pptx
 
ENGLISH 7_Q4_LESSON 2_ Employing a Variety of Strategies for Effective Interp...
ENGLISH 7_Q4_LESSON 2_ Employing a Variety of Strategies for Effective Interp...ENGLISH 7_Q4_LESSON 2_ Employing a Variety of Strategies for Effective Interp...
ENGLISH 7_Q4_LESSON 2_ Employing a Variety of Strategies for Effective Interp...
 
Model Call Girl in Tilak Nagar Delhi reach out to us at 🔝9953056974🔝
Model Call Girl in Tilak Nagar Delhi reach out to us at 🔝9953056974🔝Model Call Girl in Tilak Nagar Delhi reach out to us at 🔝9953056974🔝
Model Call Girl in Tilak Nagar Delhi reach out to us at 🔝9953056974🔝
 
ECONOMIC CONTEXT - PAPER 1 Q3: NEWSPAPERS.pptx
ECONOMIC CONTEXT - PAPER 1 Q3: NEWSPAPERS.pptxECONOMIC CONTEXT - PAPER 1 Q3: NEWSPAPERS.pptx
ECONOMIC CONTEXT - PAPER 1 Q3: NEWSPAPERS.pptx
 
Introduction to ArtificiaI Intelligence in Higher Education
Introduction to ArtificiaI Intelligence in Higher EducationIntroduction to ArtificiaI Intelligence in Higher Education
Introduction to ArtificiaI Intelligence in Higher Education
 
Grade 9 Q4-MELC1-Active and Passive Voice.pptx
Grade 9 Q4-MELC1-Active and Passive Voice.pptxGrade 9 Q4-MELC1-Active and Passive Voice.pptx
Grade 9 Q4-MELC1-Active and Passive Voice.pptx
 
HỌC TỐT TIáșŸNG ANH 11 THEO CHÆŻÆ NG TRÌNH GLOBAL SUCCESS ĐÁP ÁN CHI TIáșŸT - Cáșą NĂ...
HỌC TỐT TIáșŸNG ANH 11 THEO CHÆŻÆ NG TRÌNH GLOBAL SUCCESS ĐÁP ÁN CHI TIáșŸT - Cáșą NĂ...HỌC TỐT TIáșŸNG ANH 11 THEO CHÆŻÆ NG TRÌNH GLOBAL SUCCESS ĐÁP ÁN CHI TIáșŸT - Cáșą NĂ...
HỌC TỐT TIáșŸNG ANH 11 THEO CHÆŻÆ NG TRÌNH GLOBAL SUCCESS ĐÁP ÁN CHI TIáșŸT - Cáșą NĂ...
 
ROOT CAUSE ANALYSIS PowerPoint Presentation
ROOT CAUSE ANALYSIS PowerPoint PresentationROOT CAUSE ANALYSIS PowerPoint Presentation
ROOT CAUSE ANALYSIS PowerPoint Presentation
 
Employee wellbeing at the workplace.pptx
Employee wellbeing at the workplace.pptxEmployee wellbeing at the workplace.pptx
Employee wellbeing at the workplace.pptx
 
Judging the Relevance and worth of ideas part 2.pptx
Judging the Relevance  and worth of ideas part 2.pptxJudging the Relevance  and worth of ideas part 2.pptx
Judging the Relevance and worth of ideas part 2.pptx
 
DATA STRUCTURE AND ALGORITHM for beginners
DATA STRUCTURE AND ALGORITHM for beginnersDATA STRUCTURE AND ALGORITHM for beginners
DATA STRUCTURE AND ALGORITHM for beginners
 
How to do quick user assign in kanban in Odoo 17 ERP
How to do quick user assign in kanban in Odoo 17 ERPHow to do quick user assign in kanban in Odoo 17 ERP
How to do quick user assign in kanban in Odoo 17 ERP
 
Rapple "Scholarly Communications and the Sustainable Development Goals"
Rapple "Scholarly Communications and the Sustainable Development Goals"Rapple "Scholarly Communications and the Sustainable Development Goals"
Rapple "Scholarly Communications and the Sustainable Development Goals"
 

Knowledge sharing in coopetitive alliances

  • 1. The role of knowledge sharing and organizational learning in alliances between competitors Paavo Ritala; Miia Kosonen Lappeenranta University of Technology, paavo.ritala@lut.fi Lappeenranta University of Technology, miia.kosonen@lut.fi Abstract The increasing tendency of firms to operate in networks has given rise to the phenomenon of alliances between competitors (i.e. coopetition). Despite some evidence on the beneficial effects of coopetition, there is a fundamental paradox involved: knowledge used in cooperation can also be used in competition. Thus, it is essential to understand what kind of knowledge is shared and learned by firms in coopetition in order to understand the risks and possibilities involved. To shed light on this problem, we focus on three types of alliance-related knowledge, which all have distinct differences in the context of coopetition: first, alliance-specific knowledge can create potential value to all the participants of a specific alliance; second, alliance-generic knowledge can help firms to improve operations in all alliances; and third, alliance-external knowledge can be used in firms’ own operations, which can also be strictly competitive against the partner. To further contribute to our theoretical field, we analyze how the types of knowledge imply different levels of risk, trust and control in alliances between competitors. Keywords Knowledge sharing, learning, alliance, coopetition, trust, risk, control Introduction According to Harbison and Pekar (1998), over 50 per cent of new alliances are formed between competing firms. This phenomenon of simultaneous competition and cooperation has been named coopetition (Brandenburger and Nalebuff, 1995; 1996). It has been noted that coopetition can enhance innovativeness (Quintana-GarcĂ­a and Benavides-Velasco, 2004) and performance (Luo et al., 2007) with respect to cooperation between non-competitors. This can be explained in many ways, including the fact that competing firms are able to learn from each other very effectively (see e.g. Dussauge et al., 2000). There is, however, a fundamental paradox concerning the role of knowledge sharing in coopetition. According to several authors (Bengtsson and Kock, 2000; Loebbecke et al., 1998), knowledge can be used for the purpose of both cooperation and competition, which makes its role problematic. The nature of coopetition makes the issue of “what to share with whom, when, and under what conditions paramount in a firm’s effort to achieve a sustainable competitive
  • 2. advantage” (Loebbecke et al., 1998, p. 218). Hence, in order to create value in alliances between competitors, knowledge sharing between firms must be carefully managed. Especially when competing firms are concerned, there is always a risk of unintended knowledge spillover which might hamper the efforts of knowledge sharing and learning, and furthermore mutual value creation. However, learning in alliances is not always straightforward, because firms are able to learn many types of knowledge which all have different purposes (see e.g. Das and Kumar, 2007; Inkpen, 2000). Several studies have tried to explain how alliances between competitors should be managed in order to solve the dilemmas of knowledge sharing. These studies have mainly focused on governance issues or firm-level strategizing (Loebbecke et al., 1998; McGill, 2007; Oxley and Sampson, 2004). Some studies recognize the risks and motivations that are connected to sharing and learning knowledge between competitors (e.g. Hamel, 1991; Soekijad and Andriessen, 2003). However, none of these studies have explicitly analyzed how different types of knowledge and learning affect the management of coopetitive relationship. Thus, we focus on the question: what is the role of different types of alliance-related knowledge in coopetitive relationships? Methodologically, our study is a theoretical literature review, which contributes to the coopetition literature (and to alliance literature in general) by explicating the role of different types of alliance-related knowledge, and the conditions for knowledge sharing in terms of risk, trust and control. The level of analysis is an interfirm relationship between competing firms. Key concepts For the purposes of this study, we first need to define what we mean by the key terms coopetition, knowledge sharing and organizational learning. Coopetition, by definition, is simultaneous competition and cooperation between firms. By cooperation we refer to an alliance or a business relationship that is more than an arm’s length relationship (for a review on different alliance structures, see e.g. Contractor and Lorange, 2002). In part, competition can be characterized in Burt’s (1988, p. 358) words: “to the extent that producers of one commodity and the producers of another have identical suppliers and identical consumers, they are competitors in the same market.” By taking these definitions of cooperation and competition together, our conceptual definition for coopetition in this paper can be laid down as a strategic cooperative relationship between firms that are competitors in the same end product and strategic resource markets. The above definition has some important implications for the context of our study. First, because the relationship between the participants is strategically important, it is likely to include many features such as relationship-specific assets and knowledge sharing practices or routines (Dyer and Hatch, 2006; Dyer and Singh, 1998; Heiman and Nickerson, 2004), which enable effective knowledge sharing. Second, because the participants in this relationship are actual competitors, they can benefit from knowledge that they might obtain from the other party, and use it in their own operations. Indeed, according to Dussauge et al. (2000) competing firms are likely to have increased relative absorptive capacity (see e.g. Lane and Lubatkin, 1998), which makes commercialization of the acquired knowledge fast and easier with respect to the situation where
  • 3. cooperation occurs between non-competitors. Thus, both the benefits and risks are highlighted in this kind of a relationship. Knowledge has been identified as the most important asset for value creation (Grant, 1996). Knowledge sharing provides the actual link between individuals and the level of the organization, where knowledge and expertise attain their economic and competitive value. It is therefore important to realize what knowledge is shared, with whom, and under which conditions. In general, knowledge sharing presumes a two-way relation between at least two parties (i.e. knowing subjects), of which one communicates knowledge either consciously or not, and the other should be able to perceive knowledge expressions and make sense of them (Hendriks, 1999). Sharing is performed on a regular basis, via formal and informal channels, and even spontaneously. Knowledge, as opposed to information, cannot be disseminated as such without some shared practices or frames (Brown and Duguid, 2001). As we have noted in the above definitions, knowledge carries a tacit, less transferable dimension; hence, individuals are likely to be the key players in knowledge sharing processes also in coopetitive relationships. Sharing is most inherent for inter-personal groups (such as project teams, job groups, networks of expertise, design groups or communities of practice) which form the actual context in which most knowledge processes are likely to take place. Such groups may provide the link between the individual and organizational levels of knowledge sharing. (Soekijad and Andriessen, 2003) Organizational learning has been defined in numerous ways. One debate has been under the question of “who learns”. The first answer is that the individuals in the organization learn and the organization’s learning is the sum of its individuals’ learning experiences (e.g. Senge, 1990). The second answer is that organizations themselves are capable of learning as social entities (e.g. Walsh and Ungson, 1991). In this study, we adopt a view that organizations are capable of learning in both ways, as the individuals’ sum of learning and as organizations themselves. Similarity, proximity, quality, and the longetivity of the relationships, among others, affect how organizations learn from knowledge being shared (Argote, 2000; Zollo et al., 2002). Knowledge sharing and learning in coopetition Accessing or acquiring the partner’s knowledge – technology, individual know-how, and organizational capabilities – is often the primary objective and motivation for firms to form alliances (Grant and Baden-Fuller, 2004; Ireland et al., 2002). Furthermore, it should be noted that in the context of coopetition, firms tend to have increased absorptive capacity with respect to each other. This is possible because they have, to some extent, a common knowledge base and understanding because of their position in similar markets (Cohen and Levinthal, 1990; Dussauge et al., 2000; Lane and Lubatkin, 1998). This means that they can quickly commercialize the knowledge that they have acquired. Indeed, it has been noted that alliance members that are competitors sometimes compete on who can learn more from the alliance (Hamel, 1991). With regard to coopetition, this can lead to success or failure from the single firm’s viewpoint.
  • 4. Sometimes alliances between competitors end up in transfer of knowledge and resources to the other party (Dussauge et al., 2000), or failure (Park and Russo, 1996). Thus, firms have been noted, for example, to restrict the scope of the alliance in order to manage threats of coopetition (Oxley and Sampson, 2004). Hence, it is important to recognize that firms can have diverse learning motives in alliances between competitors. According to Argote (2000), learning from competitors significantly contributes to the focal firm’s productivity, even if firms in general do not learn as much from their competitors as from their own experience. In addition, von Krogh et al. (2001, 433) state that alliances with competitors might provide new knowledge about their strategies, technologies and personnel resources, thereby enhancing the internal capability to predict their future strategies. In general, learning in alliances can be defined either competitive or cooperative. Some authors claim that alliances are often formed in order to learn from them, and thus firms sometimes try to outlearn their partners (e.g. Hamel, 1991; Ireland et al., 2002). On the other hand, some authors underline the meaning of cooperative, reciprocal learning which is aimed at mutual knowledge creation and development (Dyer and Hatch, 2006; Dyer and Singh, 1998; Lubatkin et al., 2001). With respect to the discussion above, it is evident that coopetition entails risks of losing firm- specific knowledge to a competitor. Thus, firms might create barriers to knowledge sharing because of fear of opportunistic use of acquired knowledge. In such a context, it is fundamental to create trust between the individuals and organizations (see e.g. Soekijad and Andriessen, 2003). Collaboration in an alliance between competitors can be accomplished when people engage in social activities together and the situation involves affective trust. On the organizational level, each organization in the alliance must be willing and able to share knowledge (motivations to learn, transparency, and receptivity). The relationship through which knowledge sharing takes place also provides an important set of facilitating conditions such as trust, strength of ties, positive former experiences about co-operation in alliances, and a favorable climate. (Soekijad and Andriessen, 2003; Panteli and Sockalingam, 2005) In prior research, especially trust has been identified as a catalyst for knowledge sharing (eg. Davenport and Prusak, 1998; Miles et al., 2000; Blomqvist, 2002). Based on the above discussion, we note the importance of trust on both individual and organizational levels. Hence, we now discuss the role of trust and the related issue of risk in more detail in the next chapter. Trust, control and risk in knowledge sharing According to Blau (1964), two factors initially account for the basis of trust: relationships have a repetitive character, and achievements increase in importance in the course of time. In addition, there has to be dependency on the other party, meaning that the interests of one party are furthered only by reliance upon the other one (Mayer et al., 1995). This implies the importance of trust for knowledge sharing in cooperative relationships. In economic terms, trust here means “a particular level of the subjective probability with which an agent assesses that another agent or group of agents will perform a particular action, both before he can monitor such action (or
  • 5. independently of his capacity ever to be able to monitor it) and in a context in which it affects his own action” (Gambetta, 1988, p. 217). Psychology, in turn, assesses trust in terms of internal cognitions and affected by personal attributes, thus seeing trust as a general expectancy held by an individual or a group that the other party involved can be relied upon (cf. Rotter, 1967). Finally, many authors stress the social view on trust, being embedded in relationships among people or institutions (Granovetter, 1985; Coleman, 1990; Mayer et al., 1995). In business contexts, trust can be defined as “an actor’s expectation of the other party’s competence and goodwill” (Blomqvist, 1997, p. 282). The definition implies the two underlying dimensions of trust, competence (capabilities, skills and know-how) and goodwill, which represents the more abstract bases (moral responsibility and positive intentions) of making trust decisions. Accordingly, two types of trust can be identified: Calculus-based trust is based on a rational choice and relies on credible information regarding the other party’s intentions and competence, whereas relational trust derives from repeated interactions, and the relationship itself forms the basis of making trust decisions (Rousseau et al., 1998). This type of trust is also referred to as identity-based trust or affective trust (Coleman, 1990; McAllister, 1995). Risk and trust exist simultaneously. Trust is not needed if there is complete certainty about the results of actions: it is a solution to specific problems of risk (Coleman, 1990; Luhmann, 1988; Lewis and Weigert, 1985). Risk suggests a future-oriented, unwelcome and threatening state of the world; it is impossible to prevent, at least to some extent, and involves consequences that result from human decisions. It is thus activated by our actions. Placing trust means suspending the risk, acting as if it were non-existent (Luhmann, 1979; Sztompka, 1999). Trust also has its counterpart, control. According to Mayer et al. (1995), control mechanisms may lead to cooperation even if trust is absent, such as when sanctioning systems are in place to punish those who default. In alliances, risks can be considered as relational risks (non-satisfactory cooperation) and performance risks (alliance objectives are not achieved). There are two separate but intertwined routes to reduce risk: trust and control, which determine the total perceived risk in the alliance, yet neither of them can fully ensure a positive outcome (Das and Teng, 1998, 2001). Control can be viewed as a process of regulation and monitoring in order to achieve organizational goals; according to Leifer and Mills (1996, p. 117, ref. in Das and Teng, 2001), control refers to “a regulatory process by which the elements of a system are made more predictable through the establishment of standards in the pursuit of some desired objective or state.” In alliances, three types of control have been identified: behavior control focuses on the processes, output control is related to alliance performance, and social control involves the establishment of common culture and values. Control can be achieved e.g. through governance structures, contractual specifications and managerial arrangements. (Ibid.) Generally, control comes into play in situations where adequate levels of trust are not present (Rousseau et al., 1998). Thus it can be stated that when there are risks in the relationship, certain proportions of trust or control are needed to facilitate knowledge sharing. For instance, two-sided communication between individuals involved in a risky situation may be hindered when there is no trust in others’ goodwill and competence. Furthermore, the existence of the norm of reciprocity in knowledge sharing has relevance only in case one party is justified to believe that
  • 6. the other will adapt to it (Castelfranchi and Tan, 2002), meaning that trust lubricates norm enforcement. Consequently, without trust on the organizational level, knowledge sharing and learning are decreased if a risk such as using knowledge to competitive purposes is perceived by any party involved. Some controversies from prior research on trust and risk in alliances should be highlighted at this point. First, Das and Teng (2001) consider trust and control as mere substitutes; consequently, they conclude that trust is not a necessary condition for successful cooperation in an alliance. However, it should be noted that reciprocal learning is a deliberate and uncontrolled process, which particularly calls for interpersonal and interorganizational trust as facilitating conditions. Hence, we argue that the role of trust and control is significantly affected by the type of knowledge being shared and learned. Secondly, Das and Teng (2001, p. 254) consider control as “a more proactive approach” than trust, leading to lower risks due to directly affecting the behavior of the partner and not passively relying on a positive expectation. This, however, seems to be more an issue of approaching trust from calculative and cognitive bases, than a question of trust itself. For instance, Lahno (2002) notes that trust does not only have rational expectations grounded in given information, but about how such information is evaluated. Hence, the expectations are more like a consequence of trusting than having a cognitive state beforehand. Hence, trust inherently involves a two-way affective relationship: knowing that one is being trusted affects both the motivations and behavior of the trustee. (Lahno, 2002) All in all, knowledge sharing in alliances requires a balance between trust and control, and mutual understanding of the alliance member firms’ motivations and goals. The actual processes of knowledge sharing also intertwine interpersonal and inter-organizational characteristics and interactions. This is challenging in coopetitive relationships, because there is a need to incorporate such processes into the strategic goals of the alliance. It is therefore fundamental to understand what kind of knowledge is shared between alliance members, how sharing is affected by and how it affects risk, trust, and control. A framework of alliance-related knowledge in coopetition So far, we have discussed the role of trust, control and risk with respect to knowledge sharing in alliances. They are, however, strictly interconnected with the type of knowledge that is shared and learned. Sometimes, competitors acquire knowledge from each other in order to outlearn each other and maximize their own benefits. However, this is certainly not always the case. This means that in order to understand the challenges that exist in the situation of knowledge sharing between competitors in an alliance, the motives of learning in this kind of alliances should be carefully assessed. According to the earlier literature (Das and Kumar, 2007; Inkpen, 2000; Soekijad and Andriessen, 2003), the learning motivations of alliances can be classified in three broad categories. First,
  • 7. firms can acquire knowledge straightly related to the alliance activities of a particular alliance; second, firms can learn knowledge used to improve the design and management of other alliances; and third, firms can acquire knowledge unrelated to alliance activities, and which they can apply outside the alliance in their own operations. For the purposes of this study, we formulate a distinction of three types of knowledge that are related to the learning motives mentioned above. First, firms can acquire knowledge of how to operate and create value in a specific alliance. We label this kind of knowledge alliance-specific, which implies that it is useful in a given context with a given partner/partners. Consequently, we call the second type of knowledge alliance-generic, which describes knowledge that can be applied to alliances in general. Finally, we call the third type of knowledge alliance-external, which describes knowledge that can be used for the benefit of a focal firm, external to the alliance. Thus, we focus on three types of alliance-related knowledge, which all have distinct differences in the context of coopetition. Figure 1 illustrates the framework of the types of learning in alliances and the related challenges in coopetition. Figure 1. Types of alliance-related knowledge As Figure 1 shows, organizational learning can be divided into three distinct motivations that differ in their nature with respect to the roles of risk, trust and control, and the level of reciprocity. In the following sub-chapters, we discuss each of the motives more closely. Organizational learning Alliance-specific Alliance-generic Alliance-external Perceived risk: low -Goodwill trust -Competence trust Perceived risk: low -Social control Perceived risk: high -Behaviour control -Output control -Competence trust
  • 8. Alliance-specific knowledge Knowledge used to improve the operations of the on-going relationship is a motive that can be considered as a prospect for the success of an alliance. Learning this type of knowledge can consist of learning of both how individual and organizational aspects operate between alliance members, and how they can be developed to create more value. When knowledge cumulates about these kinds of operations, they can be called inter-organizational routines, which mainly develop in the course of time (Zollo et al., 2002). This type of learning can also be reciprocal, which can be more fruitful than one-sided learning (Lubatkin et al., 2001). In a situation, where mutual learning accumulates over the course of an alliance, trust between parties grows higher. In such a relationship, goodwill trust is often based on experiences about the other party. In a similar vein, the perceived competencies of the alliance partner reduce the perceived risk (Das and Teng, 2001). Learning by one party improves the results of another because the learning that is alliance-specific will enhance overall alliance performance and flexibility. In addition, this type of learning does not include risk of unintended knowledge spill- over; on the contrary, knowledge sharing is preferred to boost mutual learning. Thus, there is an opportunity to gain relational rents (Dyer and Singh, 1998), because parties trust each other and are therefore more efficient in governing the whole relationship and creating knowledge sharing routines. Alliance-generic knowledge Alliance-generic knowledge can be described a “neutral zone” as a subject of learning motivation. This type of learning consists of both individual and organizational experiences, practices, and skills of how to operate with another organization in order to pursue individual and mutual goals. Alliance-generic knowledge could thus be understood as part of a larger meta- capability to collaborate (Miles et al., 2000). Indeed, this type of knowledge is useful to a given firm in the long run and helps it to outperform other firms that are not as good in alliance management and practices (see e.g. Dyer and Hatch, 2006; Ritter et al., 2002). Learning this type of knowledge cannot be harmful to another firm in a distinct alliance, and therefore this type of learning does not create conflicts in a coopetitive relationship. Due to reduced levels of risk, relatively low levels of trust and control are characteristic of this type of knowledge. In the long run, alliance capability, i.e. the capability to learn in alliances in general, will relate positively to alliance performance (Kale and Singh, 2007). Thus, firms will benefit from the improved ability of their partners’ alliance capabilities in the long run, if the relationship continues. Alliance-external knowledge From the perspective of coopetition, there is an evident risk that learning unrelated to alliance activities takes place and is used in competitive operations (Bengtsson and Kock, 2000; Hamel, 1991). If this kind of learning is a motive for one party, it can be said that learning is asymmetric, and one party might exit as a winner. If all the parties that are competitors focus on learning alliance-external knowledge, the relationship might end up being a “learning race” (Hamel,
  • 9. 1991), which can deteriorate the benefits of the relationship, because parties become overprotective of their knowledge. Indeed, there is evidence that firms in coopetitive relationships narrow the scope and scale of the relationship in order to avoid risks (Oxley and Sampson, 2004). Thus, if this kind of learning takes place – as it eventually does to some extent – it is critical to balance between trust and control among parties if the functioning of the relationship needs to be secured in the long run. In the case of coopetition, it is evident that alliance-external knowledge can be used in competitive operation against the alliance partner. Therefore it is extremely difficult to accumulate trust between parties, and create opportunities for mutual value creation, if learning of alliance-external knowledge takes place. There are basically two solutions in this situation: decrease the scope and scale of alliance in order to prevent sharing knowledge from critical areas (types of control) or accept the fact that some knowledge is transferred and utilized by a competitor (calculative bases of trust, i.e. willingness to be vulnerable and carry the perceived risk despite the lack of good intentions). It must be noted that sometimes firms enter alliances in order to learn, and it is a desired outcome which all parties agree on. If the possibility of learning alliance-external knowledge exists in coopetition, a firm faces a strategic decision: if the benefits of the alliance outweigh the possible negative consequences, it is rational to share knowledge even if the risk exists. This kind of situation could be in the case where markets are just emerging and the possible benefits are very high. For example, in the ICT sector competing firms cooperate intensively in the market creation phase because of large network externalities (Fjelstad et al., 2004). Hence, we note that the bases of making trust decisions are rational in nature. Discussion and conclusions Knowledge sharing and learning in alliances between competitors (i.e. coopetition) can be challenging and risky, because knowledge can be used in either cooperation or competition. However, there are many kinds of knowledge firms can learn from alliances, which all have different implications for coopetition. For this reason, we formulated a typology of specific types of alliance-related knowledge that are all subject to different learning motives. First, alliance-specific knowledge is tied to the context of a distinct alliance, and thus this kind of knowledge increases the possibility to create value in an alliance and is therefore beneficial for all the parties. It is quite evident that when there are benefits to all the parties, knowledge sharing is increased and a possibility of reciprocal learning exists. Second, alliance-generic knowledge can be used in management of all alliances, and is therefore vital for the long-term competitiveness of a single firm. Third, alliance-external knowledge gives a single firm an opportunity to improve its own operations outside the alliance context. Learning this kind of knowledge creates a risk for the other party in coopetition, if the knowledge is used opportunistically. Thus, trust and control are both fundamentally important in order to enable the functioning of the alliance if this kind of knowledge is present. In addition, it should be noted that alliance-external knowledge can also be
  • 10. used for non-competitive purposes and thus increase the value a single firm acquires from the alliance without hurting the counterpart. Theoretically, our study makes an argument about the types of alliance-related knowledge and their implications in coopetition, and alliances in general. Our main contribution to the existing literature is the explicit recognition of each type of alliance-related knowledge by introducing the three concepts of alliance-specific, alliance-generic and alliance-external knowledge, and identifying the role of risk, trust and control with respect to them. We also highlight the importance of intertwining the individual and organizational level issues on knowledge sharing and learning in coopetitive alliances. The managerial implications of our study draw attention to recognizing that alliance members have different motivations and possibilities of benefiting from alliance-related knowledge. Especially in coopetition, the knowledge shared and learned is in a major role when risks and benefits of the relationship are assessed. Our paper is theoretical in nature and thus only a first step in assessing how firms’ learning motivations affect alliances between competitors. It should be useful, therefore, to examine empirically how learning of different types of knowledge affect the knowledge sharing and learning, management and structures of coopetitive relationships. Further research could also incorporate discussion about how trust and control evolve over time in coopetitive relationships. Finally, our theoretical ideas could be expanded onto the field to consider the different types of alliances between competitors.
  • 11. References Argote, L. 2000. Organizational Learning. Creating, Retaining and Transferring Knowledge. Norwell, MA: Kluwer Academic Publishers. Bengtsson M. and Kock S. 2000. "Coopetition" in business networks - to cooperate and compete simultaneously. Industrial Marketing Management, Vol. 29, No. 5, 411-426. Blau, P. 1964. Exchange and Power in Social Life. New York: John Wiley & Sons. Blomqvist, K. 1997. The Many Faces of Trust. Scandinavian Journal of Management, Vol. 13, No. 3, 271- 286. Blomqvist, K. 2002. Partnering in the dynamic environment: The role of trust in asymmetric technology partnership formation. Acta Universitatis Lappeenrantaensis, 122. Brandenburger A.M. and Nalebuff B.J. 1995. The right game: Use game theory to shape strategy, Harvard Business Review, Vol. 73, No. 4, 57-71. Brandenburger A.M. and Nalebuff B.J. 1996. Co-opetition. Currency/Doubleday: New York. Brown, J.S. and Duguid, P. 2001. Knowledge and Organization: A Social-Practice Perspective. Organization Science, Vol 12, No. 2, pp.198-213. Burt R. 1988. The stability of American markets. American Journal of Sosiology, Vol. 94, No, 356-395. Castelfranchi, C. and Tan, Y. 2002. The role of trust and deception in virtual societies. International Journal of Electronic Commerce, Vol. 6, No. 3, 55-70. Cohen W.M. and Levinthal D.A. 1990. Absorptive capacity: A new perspective on learning and innovation. Administrative Science Quarterly, Vol. 35, No. 1, 128-152. Coleman, J. 1990. Foundations of Social Theory. Cambridge, MA: Belknap Press. Contractor F.J. and Lorange P. 2002. The Growth of Alliances in the Knowledge-based Economy. International Business Review, Vol. 11, No. 4, 485-502. Das T.K. and Kumar R. 2007. Learning dynamics in the alliance development process, Management Decicion, Vol. 45, No. 4, 684-707. Das, T.K. and Teng, B. 1998. Between Trust and Control: Developing Confidence in Partner Cooperation in Alliances. Academy of Management Review, Vol. 23, 491-512. Das, T.K. and Teng, B. 2001. Trust, Control, and Risk in Strategic Alliances: An Integrated Framework. Organization Studies, Vol. 22, No. 2, 251-283. Davenport, T. and Prusak, L. 1998. Working Knowledge: How Organizations Manage What They Know. Boston, MA: Harvard Business School Press. Dussauge P., Garrette B. and Mitchell W. 2000. Learning from competing partners: Outcomes and durations of scale and link alliances in Europe, North America and Asia. Strategic Management Journal, Vol. 21, No. 2, 99-126. Dyer J.H. and Hatch N.W. 2006. Relation-specific capabilities and barriers to knowledge transfers: Creating advantage through network relationships. Strategic Management Journal, Vol. 27, No. 8, 701-719. Dyer J.H. and Singh H. 1998. The relational view: Cooperative strategy and sources of interorganizational competitive advantage. The Academy of Management Review, Vol. 23, No. 4, 660-679. Fjelstad Ø.D., Becerra M. and Narayanan S. 2004. Strategic action in network industries: An empirical analysis of the European mobile phone industry. Scandinavian Journal of Management, Vol. 20, No, 173-196. Gambetta, D. 1988. Trust: Making and Breaking Cooperative Relations. Oxford: Blackwell. Granovetter, M. 1985. Economic action and social structure. American Journal of Sociology, Vol. 91, 481- 510. Grant R.M. 1996. Toward a knowledge-based theory of the firm. Strategic Management Journal, Vol. 17, Winter Special Issue, 109-122.
  • 12. Grant R.M. and Baden-Fuller C. 2004. A knowledge accessing theory of strategic alliances. Journal of Management Studies, Vol. 41, No. 1, 61-84. Hamel G. 1991. Competition for competence and inter-partner learning within international strategic alliances. Strategic Management Journal, Vol. 12, Summer special issue, 83-103. Harbison J.R. and Pekar P.J. 1998. Smart Alliances. Jossey-Bass: San Fransisco. Heiman B.A. and Nickerson J.A. 2004. Empirical evidence regarding the tension between knowledge sharing and knowledge expropriation in collaborations. Managerial and Decision Economics, Vol. 26, No. 6-7, 401-420. Hendriks, P. 1999. Why Share Knowledge? The Influence of ICT on the Motivation for Knowledge Sharing. Knowledge and Process Management, Vol. 6, No. 2, 91-100. Inkpen A.C. 2000. Learning through joint ventures: A framework of knowledge acquisition. Journal of Management Studies, Vol. 37, No. 7, 1019-1043. Ireland R.D., Hitt M.A. and Vaidyanath D. 2002 Alliance management as a source of competitive advantage. Journal of Management, Vol. 28, No. 3, 413-446. Kale P. and Singh H. 2007. Building firm capabilities through learning: The role of the alliance learning process in alliance capability and firm-level alliance success. Strategic Management Journal, Vol. 28, No. 10, 981-1000. Krogh von, G., Nonaka, I. & Aben, M. 2001. Making the Most of Your Company’s Knowledge: A Strategic Framework. Long Range Planning, Vol. 34, No. 4, 421-439. Lahno, B. 2002. Institutional Trust: A Less Demanding Form of Trust? Originally in Revista Latinoamericana de Estudios Avanzados (RELEA), Caracas, 16. Lane P.J. and Lubatkin M. 1998. Relative absorptive capacity and interorganizational learning. Strategic Management Journal, Vol. 19, No. 5, 461-477. Lewis, D. and Weigert, A. 1985. Trust as Social Reality. Social Forces, Vol. 63, No. 4, 967-985. Loebbecke C., Fenema P.v. and Powell P. 1998. Knowledge transfer under coopetition. In Information Systems: Current Issues and Future Changes, Larsen T, Levine L, DeGross J (eds). Lubatkin M., Florin J. and Lane P.J. 2001. Learning together and apart: A model of reciprocal interfirm learning. Human Relations, Vol. 54, No. 10, 1353-1382. Luhmann, N. 1979. Trust and Power. Chichester: Wiley. Luo X., Rindfleisch A. and Tse D.K. 2007. Working with rivals: The impact of competitor alliances in financial performance. Journal of Marketing Research, Vol. 44, 73-83. Mayer, R., Davis, J. and Schoorman, D. 1995. An integrative model of organizational trust. Academy of Management Review, Vol. 20, No. 3, 709-734. McAllister, D. 1995. Affect- and cognition-based trust as foundations for interpersonal cooperation in organizations. Academy of Management Journal, Vol. 38, No. 1, 24-59. McGill J.P. 2007. Technological knowledge and governance in alliances among competitors. International Journal of Technology Management, Vol. 38, No. 1/2, 69-89. Miles R.E., Snow C.C. and Miles G. 2000. TheFuture.org. Long Range Planning, Vol. 33, No. 3, 300-321. Oxley J.E. and Sampson R.C. 2004. The scope and governance of international R&D alliances. Strategic Management Journal, Vol. 25, No. 8-9, 723-749. Park S.H. and Russo M.V. 1996. ‘When competition eclipses cooperation: An event history analysis of joint venture failure’, Management Science, Vol. 42, No. 6, 875-890. Panteli, N. and Sockalingam, S. 2005. Trust and conflict within virtual inter-organizational alliances: a framework for facilitating knowledge sharing. Decision Support Systems, Vol. 39, 599-617. Quintana-GarcĂ­a C. and Benavides-Velasco C.A. 2004. Cooperation, competition, and innovative capability: A panel data of European dedicated biotechnology firms. Technovation, Vol. 24, No. 12, 927-938. Ritter T., Wilkinson I.F. and Johnston W.J. 2002. Measuring network competence: Some international evidence. Journal of Business and Industrial Marketing, Vol. 17, No. 2/3, 119-138.
  • 13. Rotter, J. 1967. A new scale for the measurement of interpersonal trust. Journal of Personality, Vol. 35, 615-665. Rousseau, D., Sitkin, S., Burt, R. and Camerer, C. 1998. Not so different at all: A cross-discipline view of trust. Academy of Management Review, Vol. 23, No. 3, 393-404. Senge P.M. 1990. The Fifth Discipline - The Art and Practice of the Learning Organization. Doubleday: New York. Soekijad M. and Andriessen E. 2003. Conditions for knowledge sharing in competitive alliances. European Management Journal, Vol. 21, No. 5, 578-587. Sztompka, D. 1999. Trust: A Sociological Theory. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Walsh J.P. and Ungson G.R. 1991. Organizational memory. The Academy of Management Review, Vol. 16, No. 1, 57-91. Zollo M., Reuer J.J. and Singh H. 2002. Interorganizational routines and performance in strategic alliances. Organization Science, Vol. 13, No. 6, 701-713.