Successfully reported this slideshow.
We use your LinkedIn profile and activity data to personalize ads and to show you more relevant ads. You can change your ad preferences anytime.

Microeconomics: Production Theory

261,011 views

Published on

Production Theory
The Production Function
Total, Average, and Marginal Products
The Production Function in the Long Run

Published in: Education, Business, Technology
  • Be the first to comment

Microeconomics: Production Theory

  1. 1. Production Theory Dr. Manuel Salas-Velasco University of Granada, Spain Dr. Manuel Salas-VelascoPage 1
  2. 2. The Production Function • Production refers to the transformation of inputs into outputs (or products) • An input is a resource that a firm uses in its production process for the purpose of creating a good or service • A production function indicates the highest output (Q) that a firm can produce for every specified combinations of inputs (physical relationship between inputs and output), while holding technology constant at some predetermined state • Mathematically, we represent a firm’s production function as: Q = f (L, K) Assuming that the firm produces only one type of output with two inputs, labor (L) and capital (K) Dr. Manuel Salas-VelascoPage 2
  3. 3. The Production Function • The quantity of output is a function of, or depend on, the quantity of labor and capital used in production • Output refers to the number of units of the commodity produced • Labor refers to the number of workers employed • Capital refers to the amount of the equipment used in production • We assume that all units of L and K are homogeneous or identical • Technology is assumed to remain constant during the period of the analysis Q = f (L, K) Dr. Manuel Salas-VelascoPage 3
  4. 4. Production Theory The Production Function in the Short Run Dr. Manuel Salas-VelascoPage 4
  5. 5. The Short Run • The short run is a time period in which the quantity of some inputs, called fixed factors, cannot be increased. So, it does not correspond to a specific number of months or years • A fixed factor is usually an element of capital (such as plant and equipment). Therefore, in our production function capital is taken to be the fixed factor and labor the variable one ),( KLfQ  Dr. Manuel Salas-VelascoPage 5
  6. 6. Total, Average and Marginal Products • Total product (TP) is the total amount that is produced during a given period of time • Total product will change as more or less of the variable factor is used in conjunction with the given amount of the fixed factor • Average product (AP) is the total product divided by the number of units of the variable factor used to produce it • Marginal product (MP) is the change in total product resulting from the use of one additional unit of the variable factor Dr. Manuel Salas-VelascoPage 6
  7. 7. Output with Fixed Capital and Variable Labor Quantity of labor (L) Total product (TP) Marginal product (MP) Average product (AP) 0 0 1 50 50 50.00 2 110 60 55.00 3 390 280 130.00 4 520 130 130.00 5 580 60 116.00 6 630 50 105.00 7 650 20 92.86 8 650 0 81.25 9 640 -10 71.11 Dr. Manuel Salas-VelascoPage 7
  8. 8. Total Product, Average Product and Marginal Product Curves 0 100 200 300 400 500 600 700 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 Quantity of labor per time period, L Totalproduct(unitspertimeperiod) -40 -20 0 20 40 60 80 100 120 140 160 180 200 220 240 260 280 300 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 Quantity of labor per time period, L APandMP(unitspertimeperiod) TP MPL APL Dr. Manuel Salas-VelascoPage 8
  9. 9. Relationships among Total, Marginal an Average Products of Labor Total product Labor Labor Marginal product Average product APL MPL TP LA LB LC A A B B C C • With labor time continuously divisible, we can smooth TP, MPL and APL curves • The MPL rises up to point A, becomes zero at C, and is negative thereafter • The APL raises up to point B and declines thereafter (but remains positive as long TP is positive) • The TP curve increases at an increasing rate up to point A; past this point, the TP curve rises at a decreasing rate up to point C (and declines thereafter) A = inflection point Dr. Manuel Salas-VelascoPage 9
  10. 10. Law of Diminishing Returns Total product Labor Labor Marginal product Average product APL MPL TP LA LB LC A A B B C C • This law states that as additional units of an input are used in a production process, while holding all other inputs constant, the resulting increments to output (or total product) begin to diminish beyond some point (after A, in the bottom graph) • As the firm uses more and more units of the variable input with the same amount of the fixed input, each additional unit of the variable input has less and less of the fixed input to work and, after this point, the marginal product of the variable input declines Dr. Manuel Salas-VelascoPage 10
  11. 11. Stages of Production Total product Labor Labor Marginal product Average product APL MPL Stage III of labor Stage I of labor Stage II of labor TP 3 4 8 A A B B C C The relationship between the MPL and APL curves can be used to define three stages of production of labor (the variable input) Is the range of production for which increases in the use of a variable input cause increases in its average product Is the range for which increases in the use of a variable input causes decreases in its average product, while values of its associated marginal product remain nonnegative Is the range for which the use of a variable input corresponds to negative values for its marginal product Dr. Manuel Salas-VelascoPage 11
  12. 12. In Terms of Calculus … • Marginal product of labor = change in output/change in labor input = L Q MPL    ),( KLfQ  Example. Let’s consider the following production function: Q = 8 K1/2 L1/2 If K = 1  Cobb-Douglas production function 2 1 2 1 2 1 8   LKMPL 2 1 4   LMPL 2 1 8 LTPL  • If we assume that inputs and outputs are continuously or infinitesimally divisible (rather than being measured in discrete units), then the marginal product of labor would be: Dr. Manuel Salas-VelascoPage 12
  13. 13. The Production or Output Elasticity of Labor Q L L Q EL    Q L MPE LL  The elasticity of output with respect to the labor input measures the percentage change in output for a 1 percent change in the labor input, holding the capital input constant Dr. Manuel Salas-VelascoPage 13
  14. 14. Production Theory The Production Function in the Long Run Dr. Manuel Salas-VelascoPage 14
  15. 15. The Long Run • The long run is a time period in which all inputs may be varied but in which the basic technology of production cannot be changed • The long run corresponds to a situation that the firm faces when is planning to go into business (to expand the scale of its operations) • Like the short run, the long run does not correspond to a specific length of time • We can express the production function in the form: ),( KLfQ  Dr. Manuel Salas-VelascoPage 15
  16. 16. Production Isoquants ),( KLfQ  L K Units per time period Unitspertimeperiod K1 K2 K3 L1 L2 L3 An isoquant is a set of input combinations that can be used to produce a given level of output This curve indicates that a firm can produce the specified level of output from input combinations (L1, K1), (L2, K2), (L3, K3), … a b c As we move down from one point on an isoquant to another, we are substituting one factor for another while holding output constant Dr. Manuel Salas-VelascoPage 16
  17. 17. Marginal Rate of Technical Substitution ),( KLfQ  L K Units per time period Unitspertimeperiod K1 K2 K3 L1 L2 L3 a b c • The marginal rate of technical substitution (MRTS) measures the rate at which one factor is substituted for another with output being held constant L K MRTS    • We multiply the ratio by -1 in order to express the MRTS as a positive number • Since we measure K on the vertical axis, the MRTS represents the amount of capital that must be sacrificed in order to use more labor in the production process, while producing the same level of output: ΔK/ΔL (the slope of the isoquant which is negative) Dr. Manuel Salas-VelascoPage 17
  18. 18. MRTS When Labor and Capital Are Continuously Divisible Kd K Q Ld L Q Qd       ),( KLfQ  Kd K Q Ld L Q      0 Let’s take the total differential of the production function: Setting this total differential equal zero (since output does not change along a given isoquant): Ld L Q Kd K Q       K Q L Q Ld Kd       K L MP MP Ld Kd  K L MP MP Ld Kd  K L MP MP MRTS  In production theory, the marginal rate of technical substitution is equal to the ratio of marginal products (in consumer theory, the marginal rate of substitution is equal to the ratio of marginal utilities) Dr. Manuel Salas-VelascoPage 18
  19. 19. A Numerical Example 3 2 3 1 3 LKQ  3 2 3 2 3 1 3      KL K Q MPK Assume the production function is: The marginal product functions are: 3 1 3 1 3 2 3      LK L Q MPL If we specify the level of output as Q = 9 units, and the firm uses 3 units of labor, then the amount of capital used is: L K LK LK MP MP MRTS K L 22 3 2 3 2 3 1 3 1    unitsKKK 333339 3 1 3 2 3 2 3 1    2 3 32 MRTS This result indicates that the firm can substitute 2 units of capital for 1 unit of labor and still produce 9 units of output Dr. Manuel Salas-VelascoPage 19
  20. 20. Production Theory Econometric Analysis of Production Theory Dr. Manuel Salas-VelascoPage 20
  21. 21. The Cobb-Douglas Production Function u eKLAQ 21   • Q = output • L = labor input • K = labor capital • u = stochastic disturbance term • e = base of natural logarithm • The parameter A measures, roughly speaking, the scale of production: how much output we would get if we used one unit of each input • The parameters beta measure how the amount of output responds to changes in the inputs Dr. Manuel Salas-VelascoPage 21
  22. 22. The Cobb-Douglas Production Function 21 ˆˆ ˆ  KLAQ  • Our problem is to obtain an estimated function: • However, if we take logarithms in both sides, we have: u eKLAQ 21   uKLAQ  lnlnlnln 21  β0 This is the log-log, double-log or log-linear model Dr. Manuel Salas-VelascoPage 22
  23. 23. The Properties of the Cobb-Douglas Production Function 1. The estimated coefficient β1 is the elasticity of output with respect to the labor input; that is, it measures the percentage change in output for a 1 percent change in the labor input, holding the capital input constant 2. Likewise, the estimated coefficient β2 is the elasticity of output with respect to the capital input, holding the labor input constant uKLQ  lnlnln 210  Fitting this equation by the method of least squares, we have: Dr. Manuel Salas-VelascoPage 23
  24. 24. The Properties of the Cobb-Douglas Production Function 3. The sum of the estimated coefficients β1 and β2 gives information about the returns to scale • If this sum is 1, then there are constant returns to scale; that is, doubling the inputs will double the output, tripling the inputs will triple the output, and so on • If the sum is less than 1, there are decreasing returns to scale; e.g. doubling the inputs will less than double the output • If the sum is greater than 1, there are increasing returns to scale; e.g. doubling the inputs will more than double the output uKLQ  lnlnln 210  Dr. Manuel Salas-VelascoPage 24
  25. 25. Cobb-Douglas Production Function: The Agricultural Sector in Taiwan (1958-1972) • The log-linear model: • Regression by the OLS method: iiii uXXY  33220 lnln  iii XXY 32 ln490.0ln499.1338.3ˆln  output elasticity of labor output elasticity of capital 1.989 increasing returns to scale d = 0.891 ** ** ** Significant at 5%-level Dr. Manuel Salas-VelascoPage 25
  26. 26. Cobb-Douglas Production Function: The Agricultural Sector in Taiwan (1958-1972) 2 Zone of indecision Zone of indecision 0 4dL dU No autocorrelation 4 – dU Evidence of positive autocorrelation Evidence of negative autocorrelation 4 – dL d = 0.891 0.946 1.543 2.457 3.054 Regression including a time variable: TIMEXXY iii 064.0ln469.0ln878.0348.9ˆln 32  0.814 1.750 2.250 3.186 d = 1.939 ** *** ** Significant at 5%-level * Significant at 10%-level d = 1.939 Dr. Manuel Salas-VelascoPage 26
  27. 27. Cobb-Douglas Production Function: The U.S. Bell Companies (1981-82) errorLMKY jjjj  lnlnlnln 3210  • The log-linear model: • Regression by the OLS method: d = 1.954 (no autocorrelation) jjjj LMKY ln202.0ln373.0ln401.0461.1ˆln  ** Significant at 5%-level ** ** ** ** output elasticity of labor A 1 percent increase in the labor input led on the average to about a 0.2 percent increase in the output Dr. Manuel Salas-VelascoPage 27
  28. 28. Problems in Regression Analysis • Regression analysis may face two main econometric problems when we use cross-sectional data (data on economic units for a given year or other time period): – Multicollinearity – Heteroscedasticity • This arises when the assumption that the variance of the error term is constant for all values of the independent variables is violated • This situation leads to biased standard errors • When the pattern of errors or residuals points to the existence of heteroscedasticity, the researcher may overcome the problem by using logs or by running a weighted least squares regression • Nowadays, several computer packages (STATA, LIMDEP, …) present robust standard errors (using White’s procedure) Dr. Manuel Salas-VelascoPage 28
  29. 29. Detection of Heteroscedasticity: The Breusch-Pagan Test • Step 1. Estimate the model using OLS and obtain the residuals, ûi • Step 2. Obtain the maximum likelihood estimator of σ2: ∑ûi 2/n • Step 3. Construct the variable pi: divide the squared residuals obtained from regression (ûi 2) by the number obtained in step 2 • Step 4. Regress pi on the X’s and obtain ESS (explained sum of squares) • Step 5. Obtain the B-P statistic (ESS/2) and compare it with the critical chi-square value critical chi- square value There is heteroscedasticityThere is not heteroscedasticity B-P B-P Dr. Manuel Salas-VelascoPage 29

×