SlideShare a Scribd company logo
1
COST
BY
SOURAV DAS
98367 93076
COST FUNCTION
Definition
A mathematical formula used to predict the cost associated with a certain action or a certain level of
output. Businesses use cost functions to forecast the expenses associated with production, in order to
determine what pricing strategies to use in order to achieve desired profit margins.
The opportunity cost of an asset (or, more generally, of a choice) is the highest valued opportunity that
must be passed up to allow current use. Opportunity cost ia also called economic opportunity loss. And is
the value of the next best alternative foregone as the result of making a decision
Example – I have a TV and VCR. I can either watch a movie or rent TV and VCR.Out of 2 choices, I am
selecting one. In this example, If I watch movie, then the opportunity cost of watching the movie would
be the amount of rent that I would have earned.
Explicit costs are expenses for which one must pay with cash or equivalent. Because a cash transaction is
involved, they are relatively easily accounted for in analysis. These costs are never hidden, one has to pay
separately.
Example- Electricity Bill, wages to workers etc.
Implicit costs do not involve a cash transaction, and so we use the opportunity cost concept to measure
them. Implicit costs are related to forgone benefits of any single transaction. These are intangible costs
that are not easily accounted for.
Example, the time and effort that an owner puts into the maintenance of the company rather than working
on expansion.
2
Cost Functions
Cost Minimization and the Cost Function
Because any profit maximizing firm wants to minimize the cost of producing any given level of
output, we start with the problem of minimizing a firm’s total cost. In terms of our single product - dual
input example, the problem is to
Isocost Lines
Isocost Lines give combinations of labor and capital
representing equal cost. While similar to budget lines, there is
an obvious difference: firms have an infinite number of
Isocost Lines.
minimize pK
K + pL
L
subject to the constraint that f(K,L) = qo
To follow historical convention, we denote the prices by pK = r and pL = w. Thus our problem becomes
min. rK + wL
s.t. f(K,L) = qo
Rather than solve the problem mathematically, however, we are going to do a graphical
derivation. In this simple case, we can graph isocost lines, that represent equal expenditures on labor and
capital, much like those plotted.
The isocost lines are obviously straight lines of the form rK + wL = co. The further the line from
the origin, the higher the cost. Ideally we would like to be at the least cost, but we must also achieve our
output objective. In the case illustrated, we must operate at the point K0, L0, where the isocost line is just
tangent to the isoquant.
3
Cost-Minimizing Factor Inputs
Co is the minimum cost of producing Qo units of output. It
means using Ko and Lo to do so. Similarly, C1 is the minimum
cost of producing Q1 units of output. Obviously these values
depend on r and w.
By repeating this operation for each different level of output, we can come up with a general cost
function C(q,r,w).
Properties of the Cost Function with Respect to Output
Because the general cost function contains more than we want to use at the moment, let us hold r
and w constant and concentrate on the relation between cost and quantity. We simplify our cost function
to C = C(q).
Total Cost
The following illustrates three cost functions that embody specific assumptions about the relation
between cost and quantity. In all three cases, total cost is an increasing function of quantity produced.
(How could it be otherwise?) However costs increase at different rates. In the first case (A), total costs
increase at a faster rate than the quantity produced. Here, we save that we have decreasing returns to
scale. In the second case (B), the function is a straight line going through the origin. Here, costs increase
in proportion to output. This case is called constant returns to scale. (You should see that this is the case
with either the Cobb-Douglas or the Leontief production functions). In the third case, (C), costs increase
less than in proportion to quantity.
This is the case of increasing returns to scale.
Average Cost
4
To further the picture, consider the corresponding average cost curves is presented. In Case A,
average cost is increasing as a function of output; in Case B, average cost is constant; in Case C, average
cost is decreasing as a function of output.
Three Cases of Average Cost Functions
Case A
Decreasing Returns to
Scale
Case B
Constant
Returns to Scale
Case C
Increasing Returns to
Scale
Here, average cost
rises with output
Here, average costs is
constant
Here, average cost falls
with output
Marginal Cost
Still a third property of interest is the marginal cost curve. Mathematically this is defined as the
derivative of the total cost function (or, if you will the cost of producing an incremental unit of output.
There is a relationship between the two:
 If marginal cost is above average cost, then average cost is rising. If marginal cost is below
average cost, then it is falling.
This is a sufficiently important relationship that we will give two proofs, one not using calculus,
and another using calculus.
The non-calculus proof
Let C(qo) be the cost of producing qo units of output. The marginal cost of producing the qo
th
unit
of output is C(qo) - C(qo-1). The average cost of producing qo units of output is C(qo)/qo, while the
average cost of producing qo-1 units of output is C(qo-1)/(qo-1). Suppose marginal cost is greater than
average cost. Then
C(qo) -C(qo-1) > C(qo)/qo
In turn this means that
C(qo) > C(qo-1) + C(qo)/qo
implying that
C(qo)/qo > [C(qo-1)/(qo-1)][(qo-1)/qo] + C(qo)/qo
2
Rearranging terms
5
[C(qo)/qo][1-1/qo] > [C(qo-1)/(qo-1)][(qo-1)/qo]
The two right most terms on both sides of the inequality are equal. Thus, canceling them, we get
C(qo)/qo > C(qo-1)/(qo-1)
In short, if marginal cost is above average cost, then average cost is rising.
The Calculus Proof
To see the relation between marginal and average cost, recall that average cost is given by C(q)/q,
and the derivative of average cost with respect to q is
C’(q)/q -C(q)/q2
or, with a little rewriting
(1/q)(C’(q)-C(q)/q).
The intuitive reasoning is simple: average cost can be rising only when the cost of incremental
units exceeds the average cost of the previous units.
Some Graphs
The following gives graphs of the marginal cost curve corresponding to the three cases of the
average cost curve. In case A, the average cost curve is upward sloping, indicating MC > AC. In Case B,
marginal cost is constant and equal to average cost. Finally, in case C, average cost is decreasing so that
MC < AC. Note that, even in this case marginal cost never becomes negative. Why?
Three Cases of Marginal Cost Functions
Case A
Decreasing Returns to
Scale
Case B
Constant
Returns to Scale
Case C
Increasing Returns to
Scale
Marginal cost is above
average cost
Marginal cost and
average cost are equal
Marginal cost is below
average cost
6
As you will note, I have drawn marginal cost curves that have constant slope. This need not be
the case, as we will see in the case of the U-shaped average cost curve.
The U-Shaped Average Cost Curve
As a practical matter, most economists believe that the typical competitive firm is characterized
by a U-shaped average cost curve, where average cost initially falls as a function of the level of output,
reaches a minimum and then begin to rise. At the minimum level of AC, MC = AC. At the minimum AC,
the slope of the AC curve is zero, which is sufficient to prove that MC = AC. Finally note that the MC
cost curve must cut the AC curve from below. Thus we may draw the average cost curve and the
marginal cost curve.
The U-Shaped Average Cost Curve
Here average cost first falls, and then rises. As you can see
the marginal cost curve "cuts" the average cost curve at the
minimum average cost.
Note that I have drawn the MC curve so that it is initially falling. This need not be the case, and
we have no special interest in this issue.
Fixed and Variable Cost
It is sometimes useful to divide the firm’s costs into fixed and variable components. Fixed costs,
FC, are the costs the firm would incur if it had no output. That is, FC = C(0). Variable costs are those
that vary with output. They may either be defined as the difference between total and fixed costs,
VC(q) = C(q) - C(0).
It should be obvious that what is defined as “fixed” and “variable” depends on what time period
we are talking about. In the long run, there truly are no fixed costs, but in the short run, there may well
be.
Here is a relation between the average total cost and average variable cost for a U-shaped average
cost curve. As you will note
7
 The marginal cost curve cuts the ATC and the AVC costs at their minimum
 The minimum of AVC occurs at a lower level of output that the minimum of the ATC cost
curve
 Average Variable Cost is not equal to marginal cost
 Average Variable Cost is less than average cost
 As output grows infinitely large, AVC approaches ATC
Average Variable Cost and Average Total Cost for the U-
Shaped Average Cost Curve
Average fixed cost is continually declining, and the minimum
of AVC occurs at a lower level of output that the minimum of
ATC. MC cuts both the ATC and AVC curve at their
respective minimum.
Other Factors Affecting Cost
We originally wrote the cost function as C(q,r,w) to indicate that cost was affected by things other
than output. Here are some trick questions:
First Trick Question
 Acme Widgets’ costs are now $100, of which $50 represents factor payments to workers and
$50 represents payments to capital. (To make life easier, assume that Acme Widgets leases
all plant and equipment.). Now suppose that wage rates are increase by 100%. Will total
costs go from $100 to $150
Clearly not. If Acme continued to use the same amounts of capital and labor, the answer would
be yes. But, given the new slope of the isocost lines (the situation is illustrated in Figure 8-8) Acme will
substitute capital for labor and reduce the cost increase to less than 50%.
8
Isocost Lines with a Factor Price Shift
A change in factor prices causes isocost lines to rotate. As this
graph shows,, the minimum cost of producing Qo units is not
50% higher. Rather than stay at (Ko, Lo), the firm will move
to another point such as (K1, L1) on an isocost line below
C=$150.
Second Trick Question
 Is it possible that the higher price of labor will lead Acme to lower total costs for the given
level of output?
This is a good trick question for examinations, and sometimes people do claim that higher factor
payments can lead to lower costs. But this is nonsense. Suppose, for instance, that Acme could find a
new solution involving $60 of capital payments and $30 of labor costs (at the new wage rate). At the old
wage rate, costs would only have been $80 = $60 + $20, which would violate our assumption that $100
represented the least cost. Any manager claiming that higher wager rates lead to lower costs is simply
admitting that he wasn’t doing his job in the first place.
Third Trick Question
 Does an increase in total cost mean that average cost has gone up, and that marginal cost has
gone up?
Why a Rise in Total Cost Doesn't Mean a Rise in Marginal
Cost
9
Here, a rise in total cost leads to a different production
technology with the lower marginal cost.
Another trick question. A possible illustration of why not is given. The average cost curve shifts
up and to the right from AC to AC*, and the marginal cost curve shifts from MC to MC*. So MC has
declined.
The intuition behind this is quite simple. A rise in labor cost, say, may lead a firm to purchase a
new piece of capital. Thus the average cost will rise (see the previous example to see why it cannot fall),
but, equipped with the new machine, marginal cost may well be less.
Fourth Trick Question
 Does technological change reduce costs?
We normally mean by technological change the ability to get more output from a given
combination of labor and capital. In our terms, technological change shifts the isoquants out. And, if all
of the isoquant (or at least the portion we are currently using) is shifted out, then technological change
does reduce costs. But some caveats are in order.
Don’t confuse changes in technology with changes in technique. In the example given above,
a 50% increase in wage rates leads to a change in technique. There are always several different ways of
achieving the same objective, using what we call techniques. We all know how to mow a lawn by hand,
or with a standard lawn mower, or with one of the larger mowers that commercial services use.
Switching from one to another is switching from one technique to another. The switch in technology
comes when a new type of mowing machine is invented.
For reasons we will get to later, it is important to distinguish between firm specific
technologies and industry technologies. A firm specific technology is one that only one firm can use,
protected either by something like trade secrets or patent rights, while industry technology represents
something that affects all firms in the industry.
An example: when Apple developed the Macintosh, it patented its software, and thus froze out
competitors. When IBM came out with the PC in the 1980’s it allowed for open architecture, including
the DOS system. Other firms quickly adopted DOS, and any advantage that IBM had quickly
disappeared.
10
Technological change occurs gradually. Two examples will make the point. The original IBM
PC, not yet 15 years old, had 64 k of memory, a 64k floppy and an 8086 chip. The current system is more
likely to use 250 times as much memory, a floppy disk 20 times as large (not to speak of hard disks), and
a Pentium chip, with many times the power. Yet this change occurred gradually, and in fact represented a
continuation of the computer revolution of the last 40 years.
Fifth Trick Question
 Last year, Acme Widgets produced widgets at $5 each. This year the plant manager reports
that he can cut production cost to $4 each. Does this mean he simply was not doing his job
last year?
While it is always possible that the manager was not doing his job last year, it may also mean
something more complicated. In World War II, the Pentagon contracted large production runs of planes,
tanks and the like to specific plants. They discovered over time that the cost of producing a plane or tank
at a specific plant declined, because, over time, the plant learned all sorts of production tricks.
Economists and production specialists labeled this phenomenon as the learning curve, reflecting the
commonsense notion of learning by doing. That is, the more we do of something, the better we get at it.
Thus a firm's cost function might be a function C(qt, Qt) the number of units it produces this period, qt, as
well as the cumulative number of units it has produced, Qt. Thus over time, the firm's average cost
function shifts down because of learning by doing.
Figure 8-10 shows how the production function could shift. Imagine a firm whose cost function
is
Ct = ctqt
That is, at any time, the marginal cost of producing the product is constant. However, over time,
marginal cost declines as a function of Qt, the cumulative number of units produced.
Learning by Doing: How the Cost Function Shifts
Imagine a firm whose cost function is Ct = ctqt, but where ct is
a declining function of the cumulative number of units
produced. ct might look like this.
Sixth Trick Question
 Last year, Acme Widgets produced widgets for $5 each. This year Acme's Costs will be $4.
A new competitor, Wonder Widgets, figures that it can produce widgets for $4.50 each. Does
11
this mean that Acme was inefficient? Does it mean that Wonder Widgets stole trade secrets
from Acme?
Again, Acme may have been inefficient, and Wonder Widgets may have stolen trade secrets from
Acme. One can learn a lot by simply observing competitor. If Wonder Widgets simply purchases a
widget from Acme, and turns it over to its production specialists for study, there will be a chorus of "So
that is what they do!" It is, if you will, just like looking at instructor's old exams. The knowledge will
pay off.
In fact, there is a general principle: much technological change can confer only a temporary
advantage on its developer. We rightly have patent laws to protect new technologies, for else there
would be little reason to develop new technology. But the “high tech” firms clearly recognize that the
result of new technology hitting the market is for it to be copied, sometimes illegally, but often legally.
Thus a high tech firm cannot rest on its laurels, but must continually innovate to keep a cost advantage.
Applications of Cost Functions to Some Problems of the Firm
We can show how some of this material applies by considering two problems that a firm faces in
making production decisions.
Allocating output between two different plants
The first involves allocating output between two different plants. Suppose a manufacturer has
two plants, "A" and "B". The average and marginal cost functions for the two plants are given in Figure
8-11. As you can see, plant "A" has a higher average cost and a higher marginal cost for each and every
level of output than plant "B". While this makes for a nice graph, it is not relevant for management
decision making.
Marginal and Average Cost for Two Different Plants
The example is constructed so that plant "A" has a higher
marginal and average cost than plant "B" for every level of
output. While this makes for a nice graph, it is irrelevant for
decision making.
12
To see why, suppose management is considering producing q* units of output from the two
plants. Then it wants to find the allocation of output between the two plants that minimizes total cost of
production. Here, the only cost that is relevant is the marginal cost, and the least cost solution is achieved
when the marginal cost of each plant is equal. Even though "B" appears to be a more efficient plant, it
still pays to allocate some of its production to other the older plant.
The graphical solution is shown. Here, the marginal cost of plant "A" is measured from the left-
hand side, while the marginal cost of plant "B" is measured from the right hand side. As you can see the
two marginal costs are equated when qA is produced at plant "A" and qB = q*-qA is produced at plant "B".
Any other point would involve higher cost.
Allocating Production Between Two Plants
The least cost solution requires that the marginal cost of
operation be the same. If the firm is going to produce q* units
of output, then optimization occurs at qA.
Allocating output between a new type of plant and old plants
To see a similar problem, suppose a firm has several plants of type "A" such as illustrated in
Figure 8-13. It now becomes possible to build a new type of plant, type "B". As you can see, type B
represents a technological innovation, representing lower cost. What should the firm do? (The first thing
to recognize is that long run marginal cost is now given by the minimum average cost of plant "B". The
firm can build as many of those as it wishes, and operate them at the minimum of the LRAC.
Marginal and Average Cost for Two Different Plants
13
A firm is operating a number of plants of type "A". and it now
becomes possible to build new, more efficient plants of type
"B". This does not mean the firm should shut down its
existing plants, merely change the scale of operation. The
existing plants should not begin producing qA units of output.
That does not mean that it should junk its existing plants. It should continue to operate them
where the marginal cost equals the new long run marginal cost.
Choosing Plant Size
Now consider a different problem. A firm is considering building one of three different plants,
whose average costs are as depicted in Figure 8-14. Its long run average cost curve is then a peculiar
scallop-shaped figure, representing the minimum of each of these average cost curves.
Long Run Average Cost when Different Sized plants are
possible
A firm can choose between three different plants. Its long run
average cost curve is now the scallop-shaped figure, the
minimum of the average cost for each of the three plants.
14
It is also possible to extend this analysis to the case of many different sized plants, so that the firm
can select from a continuum of plant sizes. While, this discussion is much beloved by professors of
economics, we will not go into it here.1
Cost functions
In talking about cost functions, we have presupposed a simple cost function C = C(q). While the
precise definition of the cost function will depend on the exact nature of the firm's production function,
we often illustrate the properties of a cost function with one of two simple standard functions:
The Linear Cost Function
C = a + b q
The Quadratic Cost Function
C = a + b q + c q2
For example, the cost function
C = 3+ 5q
is a linear cost function, while
C = 4 + 5q + q2
is a quadratic cost function. The difference between the two functions is straightforward. The first cost
function simply contains q, while the second term contains q2
.
Let us illustrate some of our basic notions using these cost functions.
Fixed Cost
Fixed cost is, quite simply the costs when q = 0. It is a simple matter to show that, in the case of
both our linear and quadratic cost functions, the first term, a, represents fixed cost.
Variable Cost
Variable cost is the cost varying with output, or, if you will, total cost less fixed cost. In the case
of the linear cost function, variable cost will be the term bq; in the case of the quadratic cost function,
variable cost will be bq + cq2
.
Average Cost
Average cost is total cost divided by quantity, or C(q)/q. In the case of the linear cost function,
average cost will be
a/q + b.
In the case of the quadratic cost function, average cost will be
1 Jacob Viner, who originally did the work, was then at the University of Chicago and later at Princeton University. Viner
stumbled on this discussion by accident. He did it wrong, and only discovered his error when one of his Ph.D. students,
assigned the task of drafting the graphs reported that he could not draw them the way Viner wanted them. For this, Viner
got an important article published and the Ph.D. student got a footnote. It should serve as a reminder to readers of these
notes to check the logic carefully behind each graph.
15
a/q + b + cq.
We could also compute average fixed cost and average variable cost.
Marginal Cost
Marginal cost is simply the incremental cost of producing an additional unit of the product. The
idea is the incremental cost C, associated with producing an incremental unit of output, Q. When we
are dealing with simple production functions such as linear or quadratic functions, we customarily
compute the marginal cost by taking the derivative of the cost function. That is
In words, marginal cost is the derivative of the cost function with respect to output. For those rusty on
elementary differential calculus, remember that, in the case of our linear cost function
C'(q) = b
and in the case of the quadratic cost function
C'(q)= b + 2cq
Two Problems
Here are two simple exercises. One is worked, and one is left for you to do on your own.
Suppose a firm has a cost function
C = 10 +20q + 4q2
.
 Compute total cost, total variable cost, total fixed cost, average cost, average variable cost,
average fixed cost, and marginal cost when q=10.
 Find the value of q at which MC = AC.
 What level of output minimizes AC?
16
 At what level of output is marginal cost equal 60?
Answers
 Total cost is 10 + 20 (10) + 4(10)2 = 610. Total variable cost is the last two terms, or 600.
Average cost is 10. To compute average cost, average variable cost, and average foxed cost,
just divide by 10 to get 61,60, and 1 respectively. Marginal cost is given by 20 + 8q = 100
when q = 10.
 Average cost is 10/q + 20 + 4q. We want to find the value at which
10/q + 20 + 4q = 20 + 8q.
Simplifying, we get that
10/q = 4q
and we can solve that equation to get q2
= 2.5, or q = 1.58
 We know that MC = AC at the minimum of the AC function. Thus, from the answer above,
we know that the minimum occurs at 1.58.
 Recall that MC = 20 + 8q. That equals 60 when q = 5.
A Second Problem
Suppose the cost function is
C = 5+ 10q2
.
Compute the same answers asked for above.
1. A person managing dry cleaning store for $30,000 per year decides to open a dry cleaning
store. The revenues of the store during the first year of operation are $100,000 and the expenses
are $35,000 for salaries, $10,000 for supplies, $8,000 for rent, $2,000 for utilities, and $5,000 for
interest on a bank loan. Calculate:
a. the explicit cost
Explicit costs = salaries + supplies + rent + utilities + interest on the bank loan = 35000 + 10000 + 8000 +
2000 + 5000 = $60000.
b. the implicit costs
Implicit costs = entrepreneur forgone salary = $30000.
c. the accounting profit
Accounting profit = TR - explicit costs = 100000 - 60000 = $40000
d. the economic profit
Economic profit = TR - explicit costs - implicit costs = 100000 - 60000 - 30000 = $10000
e. Indicate whether the person should open the dry cleaning store
Since the person would earn an economic profit of $10000 per year, he or she should open the dry
cleaning store: positive economic profits.
17
2. Answer the following questions:
a. What is the slope of the line that goes through (2, 5), (8, 2)?
m = (2 - 5) / (8 - 2) = - 3 / 6 = - 1 / 2
slope = -0.5
b. What is the slope of the line for which an equation is:
6x + 3y - 12 = 0
3y = 12 - 6x
y = 4 - 2x
slope = -2
c. Is the following equation an equation for a demand or for a supply curve?
2q + 6p - 8 = 0
6p = 8 - 2q
p = 4/3 -(1 / 3)q
This is a demand curve because the slope is negative.
3. You are given the Total Cost function TC = (1/3)Q^3 - 8.5Q^2 +60Q+27
a. Derive the AC and MC functions
AC = TCQ = (1/3)Q^2 - 8.5Q + 60 + 27/Q
MC = dTR/dQ = Q^2 - 17Q +60
b. Explain the (graphical, i.e. in terms of slopes) relationship between TC and MC
MC is the slope of TC.
c. Determine the level of output at which the total cost function is minimized and the level of total
cost (Hint: You will need to check the second derivative).
We need to solve: Q^2- 17Q + 60 = 0,
(Q - 12)*(Q - 5) = 0, so the optimum are Q= 5 and 12. Checking the second derivative to see which one
of these is a minimum,
dMC / dQ = 2Q - 17
2(5) - 17 < 0, thus Q = 5 corresponds to a maximum.
2(12) - 17 > 0, thus, Q = 12 corresponds to a minimum.
At Q = 12, TC = (1 /3)*123 - 8.5*122 + 60*12 + 27 = 99.
4. A market demand is such that if price is $10 per unit, the quantity demanded is 100. For each $1
increase in price, the quantity demanded decreases by 20. The quantity supplied is zero until the
price reaches $5. Above that price, the quantity supplied increases by 10 for each $1 increase in
price.
a. Determine the equation of the supply and demand curve.
First, one needs two data points. An example is: P = 10, Q = 100; P = 11, Q = 80.
Then, we can calculate the slope: Slope = (10 - 11) / (100 - 80) = -0.05 = a.
Using (Q = 100, P = 10), we have P = b - 0.05Q, where b is the vertical intercept.
Solving for b yields b = 10 + 0.05*100 = 15.
The equation of the demand curve is therefore P = 15 - 0.05Q.
Now we can do the same thing for the supply:
The 2 data points can be for example (Q = 0, P = 5) and (Q = 10, P = 6).
Slope = (6- 5) / (10 - 0) = 0.1.
We know that the vertical intercept is 5 (see above), thus, the equation of the supply curve is
P = 5 + 0.1Q.
b. What are the demand and supply functions?
For the demand:
0.05Q = 15 - P, so
Q = 300 - 20P.
18
Similarly for the supply function, inverting the equation of the supply curve yields:
Q = -50 + 10P.
c. What is the equilibrium price and quantity?
Setting demand = supply yields:
-50 + 10P = 300 - 20P, 350 = 30P,
P = 350 / 30 = $11.67
Plugging in the demand or supply function to get quantities yields: Q = Q = -50 + 10(11.67) = 66.67.
5. Using the demand function
Q = 300 - 10P (1)
a. Determine the equation of the total revenue (TR), average revenue (AR) and marginal revenue
(MR).
TR = PQ. In order to calculate it, one needs to invert the demand function so that we can find the
demand curve equation:
10P = 300 - Q, P = 30 - 0.1Q.
Now, if we multiply both side of the demand curve equation by Q, we will have an expression for total
revenue: TR = PQ = (30 - 0.1Q)*Q = 30Q - 0.1Q2
Average revenue is defined as TR / Q: AR = (30Q - 0.1Q2 ) / Q = 30 - 0.1Q
Marginal revenue is defined as the first derivative of total revenue:
MR = dTR / dQ = 30 - 0.2Q
b.c. see class notes/ not included
d. Determine mathematically at what quantity is total revenue maximized. Check that you have
maximized not minimized total revenue.
In order to maximize total revenue, one needs to set the first derivative of the total revenue function (the
marginal revenue function) equal to 0:
30 - 0.2Q = 0, 30 = 0.2Q, Q = 30 / 0.2 = 150. At quantities of 150, total revenue is optimized. In order
to know whether we have a maximum or a minimum, one needs to check the second derivative:
d2TR / dQ2 = dMR / dQ = -0.2.
Since -0.2 < 0, we conclude that we have maximized not minimized total revenue at Q = 150.
SUNK COST
Sunk costs are retrospective costs that cannot be recovered, and are therefore irrelevant to future
investment decisions in the project which incurs them.
CHECKPOINTS
o Only prospective costs should impact an investment decision. Therefore, sunk costs are
not to be considered when deciding whether to undertake a project.
o A sunk cost is distinct from an economic loss. A loss may be caused by a sunk cost,
however.
o Sunk costs are irrecoverable.
19
Sunk Costs Examples
Let’s say a company spent $5 million building an airplane. Before the plane is complete, the managers
learn that it is obsolete and no airline will buy it. The market has evolved and now the airlines want a
different type of plane.
The company can finish the obsolete plane for another $1 million, or it can start over and build the new
type of plane for $3 million. What should the managers decide? Should they spend that last $1 million to
finish up the plane that’s almost done, or should they spend the $3 million to build the new plane?
At first glance, you may think the company should just finish the old plane. It’s only another million
bucks and they already spent $5 million. But in reality, the five million is irrelevant. It is a sunk cost. The
only relevant cost is the $3 million dollars. The managers should consider whether or not to spend $3
million on the new plane, and nothing regarding the old plane should affect the decision.
DIFFERENCE BETWEEN SUNK COST AND ECONOMIC LOSS
The sunk cost is distinct from economic loss. For example, when a car is purchased, it can subsequently
be resold; however, it will probably not be resold for the original purchase price. The economic loss is the
difference between these values (including transaction costs).
The sum originally paid should not affect any rational future decision-making about the car, regardless of
the resale value. If the owner can derive more value from selling the car than not selling it, then it should
be sold, regardless of the price paid.
In this sense, the sunk cost is not a precise quantity, but an economic term for a sum paid in the past,
which is no longer relevant to decisions about the future. The sunk cost may be used to refer to the
original cost or the expected economic loss. It may also be used as shorthand for an error in analysis due
to the sunk cost fallacy, irrational decision-making or, most simply, as irrelevant data.
Sunk Costs Fallacy
The sunk cost fallacy is when someone considers a sunk cost in a decision and subsequently makes a poor
decision.
An example of the sunk cost fallacy is paying for a movie ticket, finding out the movie is terrible, and
staying to watch anyway just to get your money’s worth. When you find out the movie is terrible, you
should make a decision whether to sit through the bad movie or to do something more meaningful with
your time – the price you paid for the ticket should not affect your decision. The ticket price is a sunk
cost.
Another example of the sunk cost fallacy is paying for an all-you-can-eat buffet, eating until you’re full,
and then going back for more just to get your money’s worth. When you are full, you should decide
20
whether you want to eat more or to stop eating – the fact that you paid for unlimited food should not
affect your decision. The price of the buffet is a sunk cost.
COST CURVES
21
22
EXPANSION PATH
The change in the optimal input bundle when output changes depends on the nature of the production
function. The path of all optimal input bundles as output increases is called the output expansion path.
The blue line in the following figure is an example of an output expansion path.
In this example, as output increases initially more of both inputs are used. Then, between the second and
third isocost lines the amount of input 2 used starts to decline.
If the optimal amount of an input increases with output then the input is called normal, while if the
amount used decreases then the input is called inferior.
Example: a production function with fixed proportions
Consider the production function F (z1, z2) = min{z1, z2}. Given the shape of its isoquants, the output
expansion path of this production function is a ray from the origin, as in the following figure. For any
input prices, the firm uses y units of each input to produce y units of output (see its conditional input
demands), so that its output expansion path is the line z2 = z1.
23
Example: a production function with fixed proportions
Consider the production function F (z1, z2) = min{z1/2, z2}. Given the shape of its isoquants, the output
expansion path of this production function is a ray from the origin, as in the following figure. For any
input prices, the firm uses 2y units of input 1 and y units of input 2 to produce y units of output (see its
conditional input demands), so that its output expansion path is the line z2 = z1/2.
Example: a general production function with fixed proportions
A general production function with fixed proportions takes the form F (z1, z2) = min{az1, bz2} for some
constants a and b. Given the shape of its isoquants, the output expansion path of this production function
is, as in the previous case, a ray from the origin. For any input prices, the firm uses y/a units of input 1
and y/b units of input 2 to produce y units of output (see its conditional input demands), so that its output
expansion path is the line z2 = (a/b)z1.
24
Example: a production function in which the inputs are perfect substitutes
Consider the production function F (z1, z2) = z1 + z2, in which the inputs are perfect substitutes. Given the
shape of its isoquants, its output expansion path is
 the z2 axis if w1 > w2 (if the price of input 1 exceeds that of input 2 then the firm uses none of
input 1)
 the z1 axis if w1 < w2 (if the price of input 2 exceeds that of input 1 then the firm uses none of
input 2)
 the set of all pairs (z1, z2) if w1 = w2 (if the prices of the inputs are the same then every
combination of inputs is optimal). [That is, in this case there is not a single output expansion
path.]
25
Example: a general production function in which the inputs are perfect substitutes
The general form of a production function in which the inputs are perfect substitutes is F (z1, z2) = az1 +
bz2, for some constants a and b. Given the shape of its isoquants, its output expansion path is
 the z2 axis (the firm uses none of input 1) if w1 > (a/b)w2
 the z1 axis (the firm uses none of input 2) if w1 < (a/b)w2
 the set of all pairs (z1, z2) (every combination of inputs is optimal) if w1 = (a/b)w2. [That is, in this
case there is not a single output expansion path.]
Example: a Cobb-Douglas production function
Consider the Cobb-Douglas production function F (z1, z2) = z1
1/2
z2
1/2
. The conditional input demand
functions for this production function are
z1 = y(w2/w1)1/2
and z2 = y(w1/w2)1/2
.
Thus the output expansion path satisfies z2/z1 = w1/w2, or
z2 = (w1/w2)z1.
As in all the previous examples, the output expansion path is thus a ray from the origin.
Long run and short run cost functions
In the long run, the firm can vary all its inputs. In the short run, some of these inputs are fixed. Since the
firm is constrained in the short run, and not constrained in the long run, the long run cost TC(y) of
producing any given output y is no greater than the short run cost STC(y) of producing that output:
TC(y) STC(y) for all y.
Now consider the case in which in the short run exactly one of the firm's inputs is fixed. For concreteness,
suppose that the firm uses two inputs, and the amount of input 2 is fixed at k. For many (but not all)
production functions, there is some level of output, say y0, such that the firm would choose to use k units
of input 2 to produce y0, even if it were free to choose any amount it wanted. In such a case, for this level
of output the short run total cost when the firm is constrained to use k units of input 2 is equal to the long
run total cost: STCk(y0) = TC(y0). We generally assume that for any level at which input 2 is fixed, there is
some level of output for which that amount of input 2 is appropriate, so that for any value of k,
TC(y) = STCk(y) for some y.
(There are production functions for which this relation is not true, however: see the example of a
production function in which the inputs are perfect substitutes.)
26
For a total cost function with the typical shape, the following figure shows the relations between STC and
TC.
Examples of long run and short run cost functions
Long run and short run average cost functions
Given the relation between the short and long run total costs, the short and long run average and marginal
cost functions have the forms shown in the following figure.
Note:
 The SMC goes through the minimum of the SAC and the LMC goes through the minimum of the
LAC.
27
 When SAC = LAC we must have SMC = LMC (since slopes of total cost functions are the same
there).
In the case that the production function has CRTS, the LAC is horizontal, as in the following figure.
Derivation of Long-Run Marginal Cost Curve
The Derivation of Long-Run Marginal Cost Curve!
Since marginal cost curve is important both from the viewpoint of the short run and the long run, it will
be useful to know how the long-run marginal cost curve is derived.
The long-run marginal cost curve can be directly derived from the long-run total cost curve, since the
long-run marginal cost at a level of output is given by the slope of the total cost curve at the point
corresponding to that level of output.
Besides, the long-ran marginal cost curve can be derived from the long-run average cost curve, because
the long-ran marginal cost curve is related to the long-run average cost curve in the same way as the
short-ran marginal cost curve is related to short-run average cost curve. In Fig. 19.12, it is depicted that
how the long-run marginal cost curve LMC is derived from a long-run average cost curve LAC
enveloping a family of short-run average and marginal cost curves.
28
If the output OA is too produced in the long ran, then it must be produced on the long-run average cost
curve LAC at point H which is a tangency point with the short-run average cost curve SAC1. Thus, when
output OA is to be produced in the long run, it will be produced with the plant corresponding to the short-
run average cost curve SAC1 and the short-run marginal cost curve SMC1.
Corresponding to the tangency point H between the short-run average cost curve SAC1 and the long-run
average cost curve LAC, there is a point N on the short run marginal cost curve SMC. This means that the
production of output OA in the long run involves the marginal cost AN. Therefore point N must lie on the
long-run marginal cost curve corresponding to output OA. If output OB is to be produced in the long run,
it will be produced at point Q which is the tangency point between LAC and SAC2.
Q is also the point on the short-run marginal cost curve SMC2, corresponding to output OB. (Q is the
common point between SAC2 and SMC2 because Q is the minimum point of SAC2, at which the SMC2,
cuts it from below). Thus Q must also lie on the long-run marginal cost curve corresponding to output
OB. Similarly, if output OC is to be produced in the long run, it will be produced at point M which is the
tangency point between LAC and SAC3 Corresponding to point M, the relevant point on the SMC3 is K
which means that the long-run marginal cost of producing OC is CK.
Thus point K must lie on the long-run marginal cost curve corresponding to output OC. By connecting
points N, Q and K we obtain the long-run marginal cost curve LMC. It will be seen from Fig. 19.12 that
the long-run marginal cost curves is flatter than the short-run marginal cost curves.
It should also be remembered that the relationship between the long-run marginal cost curve LMC and the
long-run average cost curve LAC is the same as that between the short-run marginal cost curve and the
short -run average cost curve.
Thus, when the long-run marginal cost curve LMC lies below the long-run average cost curve, the latter
will be falling, and when the long-run marginal cost curve lies above the long-run average cost, the latter
will be rising. When the long- run marginal cost is equal to the long- run average cost, the latter will be
neither rising nor falling.
Relationship of LAC and LMC with SAC and SMC:
29
It is important to note that LAC and SAC curves are related in an important way with SMC and LMC
curves. This relationship shows, as will be seen from Fig. 19.13, that at the level of output at which a
particular SAC curve is tangent to the LAC curve, the corresponding SMC curve intersects the LMC
curve.
This relationship can be proved using a short-run total cost curve and the long run total cost curve and this
has been done in Figure 19.13 where a short-run total cost curve STC and the long-run total cost curve
LTC are drawn.
It will be seen from Figure 19.13 that long-run total cost curve LTC lies below the short-run total cost
curve STC at all levels of output except at output OA at which the two curves are tangent. This means
that L4C is less than SAC at all levels of output other than OA.
As will be seen from the bottom of panel figure 19.13 that long-run average cost LAC will be equal to the
short-run average cost SAC at output OA at which LTC curve is tangent to the STC curve. But the long-
run marginal cost LMC must also be equal to short-run marginal cost SMC at output OA i.e. the tangency
point P.
This is because marginal cost is given by the slope of the total cost curve at any point, and the LTC curve
and STC curve have the same slope at the tangency point P. It will be seen from the bottom panel of Fig.
19.13 that at output level OA, where the SAC is equal to the LAC, SMC is also equal to the LMC.
30
Economies of Scope
WRITE A COMMENT
Economies of scope are cost advantages that result when firms provide a variety of products rather than
specializing in the production or delivery of a single product or service. Economies of scope also exist if a
firm can produce a given level of output of each product line more cheaply than a combination of separate
firms, each producing a single product at the given output level. Economies of scope can arise from the
sharing or joint utilization of inputs and lead to reductions in unit costs. Scope economies are frequently
documented in the business literature and have been found to exist in countries, electronic-based B2B
(business-to-business) providers, home healthcare, banking, publishing, distribution, and
telecommunications.
METHODS OF ACHIEVING ECONOMIES OF SCOPE
Flexible Manufacturing
The use of flexible processes and flexible manufacturing systems has resulted in economies of scope
because these systems allow quick, low-cost switching of one product line to another. If a producer can
manufacture multiple products with the same equipment and if the equipment allows the flexibility to
change as market demands change, the manufacturer can add a variety of new products to their current
line. The scope of products increases, offering a barrier to entry for new firms and a competitive synergy
for the firm itself.
Related Diversification
Economies of scope often result from a related diversification strategy and may even be termed
"economies of diversification." This strategy is made operational when a firm builds upon or extends
existing capabilities, resources, or areas of expertise for greater competitiveness. According to Hill,
Ireland, and Hoskisson in their best selling strategic management textbook, Strategic Management:
Competitiveness and Globalization, firms select related diversification as their corporate-level strategy in
an attempt to exploit economies of scope between their various business units. Cost-savings result when a
business transfers expertise in one business to a new business. The businesses can share operational skills
and know-how in manufacturing or even share plant facilities, equipment, or other existing assets. They
may also share intangible assets like expertise or a corporate core competence. Such sharing of activities
is common and is a way to maximize limited constraints.
As an example, Kleenex Corporation manufactures a number of paper products for a variety of end users,
including products targeted specifically for hospitals and health care providers, infants, children, families,
and women. Their brands include Kleenex, Viva, Scott, and Cottonelle napkins, paper towels, and facial
tissues; Depends and Poise incontinence products; Huggies diapers and wipes; Pull-Ups, Goodnites, and
Little Swimmers infant products; Kotex, New Freedom, Litedays, and Security feminine hygiene
products; and a number of products for surgical use, infection control, and patient care. All of these
product lines utilize similar raw material inputs and/or manufacturing processes as well as distribution
and logistics channels.
31
Mergers
The merger wave that swept the United States in the late 1990s and early 2000s is, in part, an attempt to
create scope economies. Mergers may be undertaken for any number of reasons. "As a rule of thumb,"
explained Rob Preston in an article about the trouble with mergers, "'scope' acquisitions—moves that
enhance or extend a vendor's product portfolio—succeed more often than those undertaken to increase
size and consolidate costs." Pharmaceutical companies, for example, frequently combine forces to share
research and development expenses and bring new products to market. Research has shown that firms
involved in drug discovery realize economies of scope by sustaining diverse portfolios of research
projects that capture both internal and external knowledge spillovers.
Linked Supply Chains
Today's linked supply chains among raw material suppliers, other vendors, manufacturers, wholesalers,
distributors, retailers, and consumers often bring about economies of scope. Integrating a vertical supply
chain results in productivity gains, waste reduction, and cost improvements. These improvements, which
arise from the ability to eliminate costs by operating two or more businesses under the same corporate
umbrella, exist whenever it is less costly for two or more businesses to operate under centralized
management than to function independently.
The opportunity to gain cost savings can arise from interrelationships anywhere along a value chain. As
firms become linked in supply chains, particularly as part of the new information economy, there is a
growing potential for economies of scope. Scope economies can increase a firm's value and lead to
increases in performance and higher returns to shareholders. Building economies of scope can also help a
firm to reduce the risks inherent in producing a single product or providing a service to a single industry.

More Related Content

What's hot

Introduction to poultry science
Introduction to poultry scienceIntroduction to poultry science
Introduction to poultry sciencemithu mehr
 
Chicken Production Business proposal entrepren.
Chicken Production Business proposal entrepren.Chicken Production Business proposal entrepren.
Chicken Production Business proposal entrepren.
Mrtorjakakovic
 
Production analysis
Production analysisProduction analysis
Production analysis
Milan Padariya
 
Brooding and rearing
Brooding and rearingBrooding and rearing
Brooding and rearingOsama Zahid
 
Pricing and Output Decisions in Monopoly
Pricing and Output Decisions in MonopolyPricing and Output Decisions in Monopoly
Pricing and Output Decisions in Monopoly
nazirali423
 
Keynesian Model Income Determination
Keynesian Model  Income DeterminationKeynesian Model  Income Determination
Keynesian Model Income Determination
Saurabh Goel
 
Sma techniques of costing
Sma  techniques of costingSma  techniques of costing
Sma techniques of costing
Shravya Reddy
 
Theory of the firm
Theory of the firmTheory of the firm
Theory of the firm
Prachi Porwal
 
Tradable Pollution Permits
Tradable Pollution PermitsTradable Pollution Permits
Tradable Pollution Permits
Hugo OGrady
 
Economies of scale
Economies of scaleEconomies of scale
Economies of scaleanand2419
 
Law of variable proportion and law of return to scale
Law of variable proportion and law of return to scaleLaw of variable proportion and law of return to scale
Law of variable proportion and law of return to scale
Mohammed Jasir PV
 
Production and cost (economics presentation)
Production and cost (economics presentation)Production and cost (economics presentation)
Production and cost (economics presentation)
AliAkberMehedi
 
HAPPY CHICK BUSINESS PLAN/ PROPOSAL
HAPPY CHICK BUSINESS PLAN/ PROPOSALHAPPY CHICK BUSINESS PLAN/ PROPOSAL
HAPPY CHICK BUSINESS PLAN/ PROPOSAL
ADITYA ARYA
 
Sylos labini’s model of limit pricing
Sylos labini’s model of limit pricingSylos labini’s model of limit pricing
Sylos labini’s model of limit pricing
Prabha Panth
 
Break Even Analysis
Break Even AnalysisBreak Even Analysis
Break Even Analysis
Nikhil Das
 
6. joan robinson's model
6. joan robinson's model6. joan robinson's model
6. joan robinson's model
Prabha Panth
 
Nature of Costs
Nature of CostsNature of Costs
Nature of Costs
Joseph Oloba
 

What's hot (20)

Introduction to poultry science
Introduction to poultry scienceIntroduction to poultry science
Introduction to poultry science
 
Chicken Production Business proposal entrepren.
Chicken Production Business proposal entrepren.Chicken Production Business proposal entrepren.
Chicken Production Business proposal entrepren.
 
Production analysis
Production analysisProduction analysis
Production analysis
 
Brooding and rearing
Brooding and rearingBrooding and rearing
Brooding and rearing
 
Pricing and Output Decisions in Monopoly
Pricing and Output Decisions in MonopolyPricing and Output Decisions in Monopoly
Pricing and Output Decisions in Monopoly
 
Keynesian Model Income Determination
Keynesian Model  Income DeterminationKeynesian Model  Income Determination
Keynesian Model Income Determination
 
Sma techniques of costing
Sma  techniques of costingSma  techniques of costing
Sma techniques of costing
 
Theory of the firm
Theory of the firmTheory of the firm
Theory of the firm
 
Tradable Pollution Permits
Tradable Pollution PermitsTradable Pollution Permits
Tradable Pollution Permits
 
Cost concepts
Cost conceptsCost concepts
Cost concepts
 
Economies of scale
Economies of scaleEconomies of scale
Economies of scale
 
Law of variable proportion and law of return to scale
Law of variable proportion and law of return to scaleLaw of variable proportion and law of return to scale
Law of variable proportion and law of return to scale
 
Chapter 23 pure competition
Chapter 23  pure competitionChapter 23  pure competition
Chapter 23 pure competition
 
Production and cost (economics presentation)
Production and cost (economics presentation)Production and cost (economics presentation)
Production and cost (economics presentation)
 
HAPPY CHICK BUSINESS PLAN/ PROPOSAL
HAPPY CHICK BUSINESS PLAN/ PROPOSALHAPPY CHICK BUSINESS PLAN/ PROPOSAL
HAPPY CHICK BUSINESS PLAN/ PROPOSAL
 
Sylos labini’s model of limit pricing
Sylos labini’s model of limit pricingSylos labini’s model of limit pricing
Sylos labini’s model of limit pricing
 
Break Even Analysis
Break Even AnalysisBreak Even Analysis
Break Even Analysis
 
6. joan robinson's model
6. joan robinson's model6. joan robinson's model
6. joan robinson's model
 
Lecture9
Lecture9Lecture9
Lecture9
 
Nature of Costs
Nature of CostsNature of Costs
Nature of Costs
 

Viewers also liked

AWT information
AWT informationAWT information
AWT information
Unit Nexus Pvt. Ltd.
 
News is something that we listen to
News is something that we listen toNews is something that we listen to
News is something that we listen togreatnewsupdate
 
Rice color sorter
Rice color sorterRice color sorter
Rice color sorter
Rice Color Sorter
 
Performance analysis of wireless mobile network
Performance analysis of wireless mobile networkPerformance analysis of wireless mobile network
Performance analysis of wireless mobile network
Bode Idowu-Bismark
 
Examen#2 mate iv sistemas
Examen#2 mate iv sistemas Examen#2 mate iv sistemas
Examen#2 mate iv sistemas
GochoxD
 
GAME THEORY NOTES FOR ECONOMICS HONOURS FOR ALL UNIVERSITIES BY SOURAV SIR'S ...
GAME THEORY NOTES FOR ECONOMICS HONOURS FOR ALL UNIVERSITIES BY SOURAV SIR'S ...GAME THEORY NOTES FOR ECONOMICS HONOURS FOR ALL UNIVERSITIES BY SOURAV SIR'S ...
GAME THEORY NOTES FOR ECONOMICS HONOURS FOR ALL UNIVERSITIES BY SOURAV SIR'S ...
SOURAV DAS
 
Problem statement final
Problem statement finalProblem statement final
Problem statement finalmorgannross01
 
Harley davidson india
Harley davidson indiaHarley davidson india
Harley davidson india
Vikas Gurudu
 
Shape poems pictures+ words
Shape poems pictures+ wordsShape poems pictures+ words
Shape poems pictures+ words
tckhong
 
Pratik_Nawani_Executive Summary_J025_71112110004
Pratik_Nawani_Executive Summary_J025_71112110004Pratik_Nawani_Executive Summary_J025_71112110004
Pratik_Nawani_Executive Summary_J025_71112110004Pratik Nawani
 
Group discussion
Group discussionGroup discussion
Group discussion
SOURAV DAS
 
OPERATIONS RESEARCH (OR)CLASSES
OPERATIONS RESEARCH (OR)CLASSES OPERATIONS RESEARCH (OR)CLASSES
OPERATIONS RESEARCH (OR)CLASSES
SOURAV DAS
 
Tumores de páncreas
Tumores de páncreasTumores de páncreas
Tumores de páncreas
Edd Vargas
 

Viewers also liked (19)

Great news update
Great news updateGreat news update
Great news update
 
AWT information
AWT informationAWT information
AWT information
 
Ritesh Resume
Ritesh Resume Ritesh Resume
Ritesh Resume
 
Ideate
IdeateIdeate
Ideate
 
News is something that we listen to
News is something that we listen toNews is something that we listen to
News is something that we listen to
 
Rice color sorter
Rice color sorterRice color sorter
Rice color sorter
 
Performance analysis of wireless mobile network
Performance analysis of wireless mobile networkPerformance analysis of wireless mobile network
Performance analysis of wireless mobile network
 
Pptpresentation
PptpresentationPptpresentation
Pptpresentation
 
Examen#2 mate iv sistemas
Examen#2 mate iv sistemas Examen#2 mate iv sistemas
Examen#2 mate iv sistemas
 
GAME THEORY NOTES FOR ECONOMICS HONOURS FOR ALL UNIVERSITIES BY SOURAV SIR'S ...
GAME THEORY NOTES FOR ECONOMICS HONOURS FOR ALL UNIVERSITIES BY SOURAV SIR'S ...GAME THEORY NOTES FOR ECONOMICS HONOURS FOR ALL UNIVERSITIES BY SOURAV SIR'S ...
GAME THEORY NOTES FOR ECONOMICS HONOURS FOR ALL UNIVERSITIES BY SOURAV SIR'S ...
 
Problem statement final
Problem statement finalProblem statement final
Problem statement final
 
Harley davidson india
Harley davidson indiaHarley davidson india
Harley davidson india
 
Marissa parker
Marissa parkerMarissa parker
Marissa parker
 
Empathize and define
Empathize and defineEmpathize and define
Empathize and define
 
Shape poems pictures+ words
Shape poems pictures+ wordsShape poems pictures+ words
Shape poems pictures+ words
 
Pratik_Nawani_Executive Summary_J025_71112110004
Pratik_Nawani_Executive Summary_J025_71112110004Pratik_Nawani_Executive Summary_J025_71112110004
Pratik_Nawani_Executive Summary_J025_71112110004
 
Group discussion
Group discussionGroup discussion
Group discussion
 
OPERATIONS RESEARCH (OR)CLASSES
OPERATIONS RESEARCH (OR)CLASSES OPERATIONS RESEARCH (OR)CLASSES
OPERATIONS RESEARCH (OR)CLASSES
 
Tumores de páncreas
Tumores de páncreasTumores de páncreas
Tumores de páncreas
 

Similar to COST NOTES LECTURE ALL COST CURVES NUMERICALS EXAMPLES THEORY

Cost Curves
Cost CurvesCost Curves
Cost Curves
Dr. Ruchika Batra
 
Managerial_economics_paper.doc
Managerial_economics_paper.docManagerial_economics_paper.doc
Managerial_economics_paper.doc
AbhishekModak17
 
Business economics cost analysis
Business economics   cost analysisBusiness economics   cost analysis
Business economics cost analysisRachit Walia
 
Theory of cost final
Theory of cost finalTheory of cost final
Theory of cost final
Tej Kiran
 
Costs functions
Costs functionsCosts functions
Costs functions
Dr. Shweta Uppadhyay
 
theory of cost
theory of costtheory of cost
theory of cost
Meenal Gupta
 
Chapter10 noha2012
Chapter10 noha2012Chapter10 noha2012
Chapter10 noha2012
TopanArdiansyahPutra
 
Managerial Economics
Managerial EconomicsManagerial Economics
Managerial Economics
JisjissyChandran
 
Cost concepts
Cost conceptsCost concepts
Cost concepts
Somerholic35
 
The cost of production/Chapter 7(pindyck)
The cost of production/Chapter 7(pindyck)The cost of production/Chapter 7(pindyck)
The cost of production/Chapter 7(pindyck)
RAHUL SINHA
 
Cost function.ppt
Cost function.pptCost function.ppt
Cost function.ppt
bizuayehuadmasu1
 
Cost function
Cost functionCost function
Cost functionptttt
 

Similar to COST NOTES LECTURE ALL COST CURVES NUMERICALS EXAMPLES THEORY (20)

Cost Curves
Cost CurvesCost Curves
Cost Curves
 
Managerial_economics_paper.doc
Managerial_economics_paper.docManagerial_economics_paper.doc
Managerial_economics_paper.doc
 
Business economics cost analysis
Business economics   cost analysisBusiness economics   cost analysis
Business economics cost analysis
 
Theory of cost final
Theory of cost finalTheory of cost final
Theory of cost final
 
Cost oncept
Cost onceptCost oncept
Cost oncept
 
Costs functions
Costs functionsCosts functions
Costs functions
 
theory of cost
theory of costtheory of cost
theory of cost
 
Chapter10 noha2012
Chapter10 noha2012Chapter10 noha2012
Chapter10 noha2012
 
Me 6
Me 6Me 6
Me 6
 
Managerial Economics
Managerial EconomicsManagerial Economics
Managerial Economics
 
Cost concepts
Cost conceptsCost concepts
Cost concepts
 
Cost analysis
Cost analysisCost analysis
Cost analysis
 
The cost of production/Chapter 7(pindyck)
The cost of production/Chapter 7(pindyck)The cost of production/Chapter 7(pindyck)
The cost of production/Chapter 7(pindyck)
 
Cost function.ppt
Cost function.pptCost function.ppt
Cost function.ppt
 
Cost function
Cost functionCost function
Cost function
 
Cost function
Cost functionCost function
Cost function
 
Cost function
Cost functionCost function
Cost function
 
Cost function
Cost functionCost function
Cost function
 
Cost function
Cost functionCost function
Cost function
 
SSS
SSSSSS
SSS
 

More from SOURAV DAS

Current Affairs Notes for December Month
Current Affairs Notes for December MonthCurrent Affairs Notes for December Month
Current Affairs Notes for December Month
SOURAV DAS
 
Competitive Mathematics Model Question Paper || Sourav Sir's Classes
Competitive Mathematics Model Question Paper || Sourav Sir's ClassesCompetitive Mathematics Model Question Paper || Sourav Sir's Classes
Competitive Mathematics Model Question Paper || Sourav Sir's Classes
SOURAV DAS
 
CAT (Common Admission Test) 2018 Slot 2 (Afternoon Session) Question Paper Wi...
CAT (Common Admission Test) 2018 Slot 2 (Afternoon Session) Question Paper Wi...CAT (Common Admission Test) 2018 Slot 2 (Afternoon Session) Question Paper Wi...
CAT (Common Admission Test) 2018 Slot 2 (Afternoon Session) Question Paper Wi...
SOURAV DAS
 
CAT 2018 Slot 1 (Morning Session) Question Paper With Solution || Sourav Sir'...
CAT 2018 Slot 1 (Morning Session) Question Paper With Solution || Sourav Sir'...CAT 2018 Slot 1 (Morning Session) Question Paper With Solution || Sourav Sir'...
CAT 2018 Slot 1 (Morning Session) Question Paper With Solution || Sourav Sir'...
SOURAV DAS
 
IAS CAST 2018 Paper 1 Solution || Indian Administrative Service || Sourav Sir...
IAS CAST 2018 Paper 1 Solution || Indian Administrative Service || Sourav Sir...IAS CAST 2018 Paper 1 Solution || Indian Administrative Service || Sourav Sir...
IAS CAST 2018 Paper 1 Solution || Indian Administrative Service || Sourav Sir...
SOURAV DAS
 
IAS CSAT 2018 Paper 1 - Questions With Solutions || Sourav Sir's Classes
IAS CSAT 2018 Paper 1 - Questions With Solutions || Sourav Sir's ClassesIAS CSAT 2018 Paper 1 - Questions With Solutions || Sourav Sir's Classes
IAS CSAT 2018 Paper 1 - Questions With Solutions || Sourav Sir's Classes
SOURAV DAS
 
Actuarial Science Mock Test By Sourav Sir's Classes || Probability & Mathemat...
Actuarial Science Mock Test By Sourav Sir's Classes || Probability & Mathemat...Actuarial Science Mock Test By Sourav Sir's Classes || Probability & Mathemat...
Actuarial Science Mock Test By Sourav Sir's Classes || Probability & Mathemat...
SOURAV DAS
 
IIT JAM Biological Sciences 2019 Full Question Paper || Sourav Sir's Classes
IIT JAM Biological Sciences 2019 Full Question Paper || Sourav Sir's ClassesIIT JAM Biological Sciences 2019 Full Question Paper || Sourav Sir's Classes
IIT JAM Biological Sciences 2019 Full Question Paper || Sourav Sir's Classes
SOURAV DAS
 
IIT JAM Geology 2019 Full Question Paper || Sourav Sir's Classes
IIT JAM Geology 2019 Full Question Paper || Sourav Sir's ClassesIIT JAM Geology 2019 Full Question Paper || Sourav Sir's Classes
IIT JAM Geology 2019 Full Question Paper || Sourav Sir's Classes
SOURAV DAS
 
IIT JAM Chemistry || 2019 Full Question Paper || Sourav Sir's Classes
IIT JAM Chemistry || 2019 Full Question Paper || Sourav Sir's ClassesIIT JAM Chemistry || 2019 Full Question Paper || Sourav Sir's Classes
IIT JAM Chemistry || 2019 Full Question Paper || Sourav Sir's Classes
SOURAV DAS
 
GATE Physics Question Paper 2017 || Graduate Aptitude Test in Engineering |...
GATE Physics Question Paper 2017 ||  Graduate Aptitude Test in Engineering  |...GATE Physics Question Paper 2017 ||  Graduate Aptitude Test in Engineering  |...
GATE Physics Question Paper 2017 || Graduate Aptitude Test in Engineering |...
SOURAV DAS
 
GATE (Graduate Aptitude Test in Engineering) Physics Preparation || Question ...
GATE (Graduate Aptitude Test in Engineering) Physics Preparation || Question ...GATE (Graduate Aptitude Test in Engineering) Physics Preparation || Question ...
GATE (Graduate Aptitude Test in Engineering) Physics Preparation || Question ...
SOURAV DAS
 
GATE (Graduate Aptitude Test in Engineering) || Physics Full Question Paper 2...
GATE (Graduate Aptitude Test in Engineering) || Physics Full Question Paper 2...GATE (Graduate Aptitude Test in Engineering) || Physics Full Question Paper 2...
GATE (Graduate Aptitude Test in Engineering) || Physics Full Question Paper 2...
SOURAV DAS
 
GATE - Graduate Aptitude Test in Engineering || Physics Question Paper 2016 |...
GATE - Graduate Aptitude Test in Engineering || Physics Question Paper 2016 |...GATE - Graduate Aptitude Test in Engineering || Physics Question Paper 2016 |...
GATE - Graduate Aptitude Test in Engineering || Physics Question Paper 2016 |...
SOURAV DAS
 
GRE (Graduate Record Examinations) English Preparation Tips || Sourav Sir's C...
GRE (Graduate Record Examinations) English Preparation Tips || Sourav Sir's C...GRE (Graduate Record Examinations) English Preparation Tips || Sourav Sir's C...
GRE (Graduate Record Examinations) English Preparation Tips || Sourav Sir's C...
SOURAV DAS
 
GATE Math 2016 Question Paper | Sourav Sir's Classes
GATE Math 2016 Question Paper | Sourav Sir's ClassesGATE Math 2016 Question Paper | Sourav Sir's Classes
GATE Math 2016 Question Paper | Sourav Sir's Classes
SOURAV DAS
 
GATE Math 2013 Question Paper | Sourav Sir's Classes
GATE Math 2013 Question Paper | Sourav Sir's ClassesGATE Math 2013 Question Paper | Sourav Sir's Classes
GATE Math 2013 Question Paper | Sourav Sir's Classes
SOURAV DAS
 
GATE Math 2015 Question Paper | Sourav Sir's Classes
GATE Math 2015 Question Paper | Sourav Sir's ClassesGATE Math 2015 Question Paper | Sourav Sir's Classes
GATE Math 2015 Question Paper | Sourav Sir's Classes
SOURAV DAS
 
GATE Math 2017 Question Paper | Sourav Sir's Classes
GATE Math 2017 Question Paper | Sourav Sir's ClassesGATE Math 2017 Question Paper | Sourav Sir's Classes
GATE Math 2017 Question Paper | Sourav Sir's Classes
SOURAV DAS
 
GATE Chemistry 2013 Question Paper | Sourav Sir's Classes
GATE Chemistry 2013 Question Paper | Sourav Sir's ClassesGATE Chemistry 2013 Question Paper | Sourav Sir's Classes
GATE Chemistry 2013 Question Paper | Sourav Sir's Classes
SOURAV DAS
 

More from SOURAV DAS (20)

Current Affairs Notes for December Month
Current Affairs Notes for December MonthCurrent Affairs Notes for December Month
Current Affairs Notes for December Month
 
Competitive Mathematics Model Question Paper || Sourav Sir's Classes
Competitive Mathematics Model Question Paper || Sourav Sir's ClassesCompetitive Mathematics Model Question Paper || Sourav Sir's Classes
Competitive Mathematics Model Question Paper || Sourav Sir's Classes
 
CAT (Common Admission Test) 2018 Slot 2 (Afternoon Session) Question Paper Wi...
CAT (Common Admission Test) 2018 Slot 2 (Afternoon Session) Question Paper Wi...CAT (Common Admission Test) 2018 Slot 2 (Afternoon Session) Question Paper Wi...
CAT (Common Admission Test) 2018 Slot 2 (Afternoon Session) Question Paper Wi...
 
CAT 2018 Slot 1 (Morning Session) Question Paper With Solution || Sourav Sir'...
CAT 2018 Slot 1 (Morning Session) Question Paper With Solution || Sourav Sir'...CAT 2018 Slot 1 (Morning Session) Question Paper With Solution || Sourav Sir'...
CAT 2018 Slot 1 (Morning Session) Question Paper With Solution || Sourav Sir'...
 
IAS CAST 2018 Paper 1 Solution || Indian Administrative Service || Sourav Sir...
IAS CAST 2018 Paper 1 Solution || Indian Administrative Service || Sourav Sir...IAS CAST 2018 Paper 1 Solution || Indian Administrative Service || Sourav Sir...
IAS CAST 2018 Paper 1 Solution || Indian Administrative Service || Sourav Sir...
 
IAS CSAT 2018 Paper 1 - Questions With Solutions || Sourav Sir's Classes
IAS CSAT 2018 Paper 1 - Questions With Solutions || Sourav Sir's ClassesIAS CSAT 2018 Paper 1 - Questions With Solutions || Sourav Sir's Classes
IAS CSAT 2018 Paper 1 - Questions With Solutions || Sourav Sir's Classes
 
Actuarial Science Mock Test By Sourav Sir's Classes || Probability & Mathemat...
Actuarial Science Mock Test By Sourav Sir's Classes || Probability & Mathemat...Actuarial Science Mock Test By Sourav Sir's Classes || Probability & Mathemat...
Actuarial Science Mock Test By Sourav Sir's Classes || Probability & Mathemat...
 
IIT JAM Biological Sciences 2019 Full Question Paper || Sourav Sir's Classes
IIT JAM Biological Sciences 2019 Full Question Paper || Sourav Sir's ClassesIIT JAM Biological Sciences 2019 Full Question Paper || Sourav Sir's Classes
IIT JAM Biological Sciences 2019 Full Question Paper || Sourav Sir's Classes
 
IIT JAM Geology 2019 Full Question Paper || Sourav Sir's Classes
IIT JAM Geology 2019 Full Question Paper || Sourav Sir's ClassesIIT JAM Geology 2019 Full Question Paper || Sourav Sir's Classes
IIT JAM Geology 2019 Full Question Paper || Sourav Sir's Classes
 
IIT JAM Chemistry || 2019 Full Question Paper || Sourav Sir's Classes
IIT JAM Chemistry || 2019 Full Question Paper || Sourav Sir's ClassesIIT JAM Chemistry || 2019 Full Question Paper || Sourav Sir's Classes
IIT JAM Chemistry || 2019 Full Question Paper || Sourav Sir's Classes
 
GATE Physics Question Paper 2017 || Graduate Aptitude Test in Engineering |...
GATE Physics Question Paper 2017 ||  Graduate Aptitude Test in Engineering  |...GATE Physics Question Paper 2017 ||  Graduate Aptitude Test in Engineering  |...
GATE Physics Question Paper 2017 || Graduate Aptitude Test in Engineering |...
 
GATE (Graduate Aptitude Test in Engineering) Physics Preparation || Question ...
GATE (Graduate Aptitude Test in Engineering) Physics Preparation || Question ...GATE (Graduate Aptitude Test in Engineering) Physics Preparation || Question ...
GATE (Graduate Aptitude Test in Engineering) Physics Preparation || Question ...
 
GATE (Graduate Aptitude Test in Engineering) || Physics Full Question Paper 2...
GATE (Graduate Aptitude Test in Engineering) || Physics Full Question Paper 2...GATE (Graduate Aptitude Test in Engineering) || Physics Full Question Paper 2...
GATE (Graduate Aptitude Test in Engineering) || Physics Full Question Paper 2...
 
GATE - Graduate Aptitude Test in Engineering || Physics Question Paper 2016 |...
GATE - Graduate Aptitude Test in Engineering || Physics Question Paper 2016 |...GATE - Graduate Aptitude Test in Engineering || Physics Question Paper 2016 |...
GATE - Graduate Aptitude Test in Engineering || Physics Question Paper 2016 |...
 
GRE (Graduate Record Examinations) English Preparation Tips || Sourav Sir's C...
GRE (Graduate Record Examinations) English Preparation Tips || Sourav Sir's C...GRE (Graduate Record Examinations) English Preparation Tips || Sourav Sir's C...
GRE (Graduate Record Examinations) English Preparation Tips || Sourav Sir's C...
 
GATE Math 2016 Question Paper | Sourav Sir's Classes
GATE Math 2016 Question Paper | Sourav Sir's ClassesGATE Math 2016 Question Paper | Sourav Sir's Classes
GATE Math 2016 Question Paper | Sourav Sir's Classes
 
GATE Math 2013 Question Paper | Sourav Sir's Classes
GATE Math 2013 Question Paper | Sourav Sir's ClassesGATE Math 2013 Question Paper | Sourav Sir's Classes
GATE Math 2013 Question Paper | Sourav Sir's Classes
 
GATE Math 2015 Question Paper | Sourav Sir's Classes
GATE Math 2015 Question Paper | Sourav Sir's ClassesGATE Math 2015 Question Paper | Sourav Sir's Classes
GATE Math 2015 Question Paper | Sourav Sir's Classes
 
GATE Math 2017 Question Paper | Sourav Sir's Classes
GATE Math 2017 Question Paper | Sourav Sir's ClassesGATE Math 2017 Question Paper | Sourav Sir's Classes
GATE Math 2017 Question Paper | Sourav Sir's Classes
 
GATE Chemistry 2013 Question Paper | Sourav Sir's Classes
GATE Chemistry 2013 Question Paper | Sourav Sir's ClassesGATE Chemistry 2013 Question Paper | Sourav Sir's Classes
GATE Chemistry 2013 Question Paper | Sourav Sir's Classes
 

Recently uploaded

Overview on Edible Vaccine: Pros & Cons with Mechanism
Overview on Edible Vaccine: Pros & Cons with MechanismOverview on Edible Vaccine: Pros & Cons with Mechanism
Overview on Edible Vaccine: Pros & Cons with Mechanism
DeeptiGupta154
 
Operation Blue Star - Saka Neela Tara
Operation Blue Star   -  Saka Neela TaraOperation Blue Star   -  Saka Neela Tara
Operation Blue Star - Saka Neela Tara
Balvir Singh
 
678020731-Sumas-y-Restas-Para-Colorear.pdf
678020731-Sumas-y-Restas-Para-Colorear.pdf678020731-Sumas-y-Restas-Para-Colorear.pdf
678020731-Sumas-y-Restas-Para-Colorear.pdf
CarlosHernanMontoyab2
 
special B.ed 2nd year old paper_20240531.pdf
special B.ed 2nd year old paper_20240531.pdfspecial B.ed 2nd year old paper_20240531.pdf
special B.ed 2nd year old paper_20240531.pdf
Special education needs
 
Honest Reviews of Tim Han LMA Course Program.pptx
Honest Reviews of Tim Han LMA Course Program.pptxHonest Reviews of Tim Han LMA Course Program.pptx
Honest Reviews of Tim Han LMA Course Program.pptx
timhan337
 
Guidance_and_Counselling.pdf B.Ed. 4th Semester
Guidance_and_Counselling.pdf B.Ed. 4th SemesterGuidance_and_Counselling.pdf B.Ed. 4th Semester
Guidance_and_Counselling.pdf B.Ed. 4th Semester
Atul Kumar Singh
 
Phrasal Verbs.XXXXXXXXXXXXXXXXXXXXXXXXXX
Phrasal Verbs.XXXXXXXXXXXXXXXXXXXXXXXXXXPhrasal Verbs.XXXXXXXXXXXXXXXXXXXXXXXXXX
Phrasal Verbs.XXXXXXXXXXXXXXXXXXXXXXXXXX
MIRIAMSALINAS13
 
Francesca Gottschalk - How can education support child empowerment.pptx
Francesca Gottschalk - How can education support child empowerment.pptxFrancesca Gottschalk - How can education support child empowerment.pptx
Francesca Gottschalk - How can education support child empowerment.pptx
EduSkills OECD
 
Sha'Carri Richardson Presentation 202345
Sha'Carri Richardson Presentation 202345Sha'Carri Richardson Presentation 202345
Sha'Carri Richardson Presentation 202345
beazzy04
 
Language Across the Curriculm LAC B.Ed.
Language Across the  Curriculm LAC B.Ed.Language Across the  Curriculm LAC B.Ed.
Language Across the Curriculm LAC B.Ed.
Atul Kumar Singh
 
Acetabularia Information For Class 9 .docx
Acetabularia Information For Class 9  .docxAcetabularia Information For Class 9  .docx
Acetabularia Information For Class 9 .docx
vaibhavrinwa19
 
How libraries can support authors with open access requirements for UKRI fund...
How libraries can support authors with open access requirements for UKRI fund...How libraries can support authors with open access requirements for UKRI fund...
How libraries can support authors with open access requirements for UKRI fund...
Jisc
 
The approach at University of Liverpool.pptx
The approach at University of Liverpool.pptxThe approach at University of Liverpool.pptx
The approach at University of Liverpool.pptx
Jisc
 
Additional Benefits for Employee Website.pdf
Additional Benefits for Employee Website.pdfAdditional Benefits for Employee Website.pdf
Additional Benefits for Employee Website.pdf
joachimlavalley1
 
The geography of Taylor Swift - some ideas
The geography of Taylor Swift - some ideasThe geography of Taylor Swift - some ideas
The geography of Taylor Swift - some ideas
GeoBlogs
 
TESDA TM1 REVIEWER FOR NATIONAL ASSESSMENT WRITTEN AND ORAL QUESTIONS WITH A...
TESDA TM1 REVIEWER  FOR NATIONAL ASSESSMENT WRITTEN AND ORAL QUESTIONS WITH A...TESDA TM1 REVIEWER  FOR NATIONAL ASSESSMENT WRITTEN AND ORAL QUESTIONS WITH A...
TESDA TM1 REVIEWER FOR NATIONAL ASSESSMENT WRITTEN AND ORAL QUESTIONS WITH A...
EugeneSaldivar
 
Unit 8 - Information and Communication Technology (Paper I).pdf
Unit 8 - Information and Communication Technology (Paper I).pdfUnit 8 - Information and Communication Technology (Paper I).pdf
Unit 8 - Information and Communication Technology (Paper I).pdf
Thiyagu K
 
Model Attribute Check Company Auto Property
Model Attribute  Check Company Auto PropertyModel Attribute  Check Company Auto Property
Model Attribute Check Company Auto Property
Celine George
 
CACJapan - GROUP Presentation 1- Wk 4.pdf
CACJapan - GROUP Presentation 1- Wk 4.pdfCACJapan - GROUP Presentation 1- Wk 4.pdf
CACJapan - GROUP Presentation 1- Wk 4.pdf
camakaiclarkmusic
 
Supporting (UKRI) OA monographs at Salford.pptx
Supporting (UKRI) OA monographs at Salford.pptxSupporting (UKRI) OA monographs at Salford.pptx
Supporting (UKRI) OA monographs at Salford.pptx
Jisc
 

Recently uploaded (20)

Overview on Edible Vaccine: Pros & Cons with Mechanism
Overview on Edible Vaccine: Pros & Cons with MechanismOverview on Edible Vaccine: Pros & Cons with Mechanism
Overview on Edible Vaccine: Pros & Cons with Mechanism
 
Operation Blue Star - Saka Neela Tara
Operation Blue Star   -  Saka Neela TaraOperation Blue Star   -  Saka Neela Tara
Operation Blue Star - Saka Neela Tara
 
678020731-Sumas-y-Restas-Para-Colorear.pdf
678020731-Sumas-y-Restas-Para-Colorear.pdf678020731-Sumas-y-Restas-Para-Colorear.pdf
678020731-Sumas-y-Restas-Para-Colorear.pdf
 
special B.ed 2nd year old paper_20240531.pdf
special B.ed 2nd year old paper_20240531.pdfspecial B.ed 2nd year old paper_20240531.pdf
special B.ed 2nd year old paper_20240531.pdf
 
Honest Reviews of Tim Han LMA Course Program.pptx
Honest Reviews of Tim Han LMA Course Program.pptxHonest Reviews of Tim Han LMA Course Program.pptx
Honest Reviews of Tim Han LMA Course Program.pptx
 
Guidance_and_Counselling.pdf B.Ed. 4th Semester
Guidance_and_Counselling.pdf B.Ed. 4th SemesterGuidance_and_Counselling.pdf B.Ed. 4th Semester
Guidance_and_Counselling.pdf B.Ed. 4th Semester
 
Phrasal Verbs.XXXXXXXXXXXXXXXXXXXXXXXXXX
Phrasal Verbs.XXXXXXXXXXXXXXXXXXXXXXXXXXPhrasal Verbs.XXXXXXXXXXXXXXXXXXXXXXXXXX
Phrasal Verbs.XXXXXXXXXXXXXXXXXXXXXXXXXX
 
Francesca Gottschalk - How can education support child empowerment.pptx
Francesca Gottschalk - How can education support child empowerment.pptxFrancesca Gottschalk - How can education support child empowerment.pptx
Francesca Gottschalk - How can education support child empowerment.pptx
 
Sha'Carri Richardson Presentation 202345
Sha'Carri Richardson Presentation 202345Sha'Carri Richardson Presentation 202345
Sha'Carri Richardson Presentation 202345
 
Language Across the Curriculm LAC B.Ed.
Language Across the  Curriculm LAC B.Ed.Language Across the  Curriculm LAC B.Ed.
Language Across the Curriculm LAC B.Ed.
 
Acetabularia Information For Class 9 .docx
Acetabularia Information For Class 9  .docxAcetabularia Information For Class 9  .docx
Acetabularia Information For Class 9 .docx
 
How libraries can support authors with open access requirements for UKRI fund...
How libraries can support authors with open access requirements for UKRI fund...How libraries can support authors with open access requirements for UKRI fund...
How libraries can support authors with open access requirements for UKRI fund...
 
The approach at University of Liverpool.pptx
The approach at University of Liverpool.pptxThe approach at University of Liverpool.pptx
The approach at University of Liverpool.pptx
 
Additional Benefits for Employee Website.pdf
Additional Benefits for Employee Website.pdfAdditional Benefits for Employee Website.pdf
Additional Benefits for Employee Website.pdf
 
The geography of Taylor Swift - some ideas
The geography of Taylor Swift - some ideasThe geography of Taylor Swift - some ideas
The geography of Taylor Swift - some ideas
 
TESDA TM1 REVIEWER FOR NATIONAL ASSESSMENT WRITTEN AND ORAL QUESTIONS WITH A...
TESDA TM1 REVIEWER  FOR NATIONAL ASSESSMENT WRITTEN AND ORAL QUESTIONS WITH A...TESDA TM1 REVIEWER  FOR NATIONAL ASSESSMENT WRITTEN AND ORAL QUESTIONS WITH A...
TESDA TM1 REVIEWER FOR NATIONAL ASSESSMENT WRITTEN AND ORAL QUESTIONS WITH A...
 
Unit 8 - Information and Communication Technology (Paper I).pdf
Unit 8 - Information and Communication Technology (Paper I).pdfUnit 8 - Information and Communication Technology (Paper I).pdf
Unit 8 - Information and Communication Technology (Paper I).pdf
 
Model Attribute Check Company Auto Property
Model Attribute  Check Company Auto PropertyModel Attribute  Check Company Auto Property
Model Attribute Check Company Auto Property
 
CACJapan - GROUP Presentation 1- Wk 4.pdf
CACJapan - GROUP Presentation 1- Wk 4.pdfCACJapan - GROUP Presentation 1- Wk 4.pdf
CACJapan - GROUP Presentation 1- Wk 4.pdf
 
Supporting (UKRI) OA monographs at Salford.pptx
Supporting (UKRI) OA monographs at Salford.pptxSupporting (UKRI) OA monographs at Salford.pptx
Supporting (UKRI) OA monographs at Salford.pptx
 

COST NOTES LECTURE ALL COST CURVES NUMERICALS EXAMPLES THEORY

  • 1. 1 COST BY SOURAV DAS 98367 93076 COST FUNCTION Definition A mathematical formula used to predict the cost associated with a certain action or a certain level of output. Businesses use cost functions to forecast the expenses associated with production, in order to determine what pricing strategies to use in order to achieve desired profit margins. The opportunity cost of an asset (or, more generally, of a choice) is the highest valued opportunity that must be passed up to allow current use. Opportunity cost ia also called economic opportunity loss. And is the value of the next best alternative foregone as the result of making a decision Example – I have a TV and VCR. I can either watch a movie or rent TV and VCR.Out of 2 choices, I am selecting one. In this example, If I watch movie, then the opportunity cost of watching the movie would be the amount of rent that I would have earned. Explicit costs are expenses for which one must pay with cash or equivalent. Because a cash transaction is involved, they are relatively easily accounted for in analysis. These costs are never hidden, one has to pay separately. Example- Electricity Bill, wages to workers etc. Implicit costs do not involve a cash transaction, and so we use the opportunity cost concept to measure them. Implicit costs are related to forgone benefits of any single transaction. These are intangible costs that are not easily accounted for. Example, the time and effort that an owner puts into the maintenance of the company rather than working on expansion.
  • 2. 2 Cost Functions Cost Minimization and the Cost Function Because any profit maximizing firm wants to minimize the cost of producing any given level of output, we start with the problem of minimizing a firm’s total cost. In terms of our single product - dual input example, the problem is to Isocost Lines Isocost Lines give combinations of labor and capital representing equal cost. While similar to budget lines, there is an obvious difference: firms have an infinite number of Isocost Lines. minimize pK K + pL L subject to the constraint that f(K,L) = qo To follow historical convention, we denote the prices by pK = r and pL = w. Thus our problem becomes min. rK + wL s.t. f(K,L) = qo Rather than solve the problem mathematically, however, we are going to do a graphical derivation. In this simple case, we can graph isocost lines, that represent equal expenditures on labor and capital, much like those plotted. The isocost lines are obviously straight lines of the form rK + wL = co. The further the line from the origin, the higher the cost. Ideally we would like to be at the least cost, but we must also achieve our output objective. In the case illustrated, we must operate at the point K0, L0, where the isocost line is just tangent to the isoquant.
  • 3. 3 Cost-Minimizing Factor Inputs Co is the minimum cost of producing Qo units of output. It means using Ko and Lo to do so. Similarly, C1 is the minimum cost of producing Q1 units of output. Obviously these values depend on r and w. By repeating this operation for each different level of output, we can come up with a general cost function C(q,r,w). Properties of the Cost Function with Respect to Output Because the general cost function contains more than we want to use at the moment, let us hold r and w constant and concentrate on the relation between cost and quantity. We simplify our cost function to C = C(q). Total Cost The following illustrates three cost functions that embody specific assumptions about the relation between cost and quantity. In all three cases, total cost is an increasing function of quantity produced. (How could it be otherwise?) However costs increase at different rates. In the first case (A), total costs increase at a faster rate than the quantity produced. Here, we save that we have decreasing returns to scale. In the second case (B), the function is a straight line going through the origin. Here, costs increase in proportion to output. This case is called constant returns to scale. (You should see that this is the case with either the Cobb-Douglas or the Leontief production functions). In the third case, (C), costs increase less than in proportion to quantity. This is the case of increasing returns to scale. Average Cost
  • 4. 4 To further the picture, consider the corresponding average cost curves is presented. In Case A, average cost is increasing as a function of output; in Case B, average cost is constant; in Case C, average cost is decreasing as a function of output. Three Cases of Average Cost Functions Case A Decreasing Returns to Scale Case B Constant Returns to Scale Case C Increasing Returns to Scale Here, average cost rises with output Here, average costs is constant Here, average cost falls with output Marginal Cost Still a third property of interest is the marginal cost curve. Mathematically this is defined as the derivative of the total cost function (or, if you will the cost of producing an incremental unit of output. There is a relationship between the two:  If marginal cost is above average cost, then average cost is rising. If marginal cost is below average cost, then it is falling. This is a sufficiently important relationship that we will give two proofs, one not using calculus, and another using calculus. The non-calculus proof Let C(qo) be the cost of producing qo units of output. The marginal cost of producing the qo th unit of output is C(qo) - C(qo-1). The average cost of producing qo units of output is C(qo)/qo, while the average cost of producing qo-1 units of output is C(qo-1)/(qo-1). Suppose marginal cost is greater than average cost. Then C(qo) -C(qo-1) > C(qo)/qo In turn this means that C(qo) > C(qo-1) + C(qo)/qo implying that C(qo)/qo > [C(qo-1)/(qo-1)][(qo-1)/qo] + C(qo)/qo 2 Rearranging terms
  • 5. 5 [C(qo)/qo][1-1/qo] > [C(qo-1)/(qo-1)][(qo-1)/qo] The two right most terms on both sides of the inequality are equal. Thus, canceling them, we get C(qo)/qo > C(qo-1)/(qo-1) In short, if marginal cost is above average cost, then average cost is rising. The Calculus Proof To see the relation between marginal and average cost, recall that average cost is given by C(q)/q, and the derivative of average cost with respect to q is C’(q)/q -C(q)/q2 or, with a little rewriting (1/q)(C’(q)-C(q)/q). The intuitive reasoning is simple: average cost can be rising only when the cost of incremental units exceeds the average cost of the previous units. Some Graphs The following gives graphs of the marginal cost curve corresponding to the three cases of the average cost curve. In case A, the average cost curve is upward sloping, indicating MC > AC. In Case B, marginal cost is constant and equal to average cost. Finally, in case C, average cost is decreasing so that MC < AC. Note that, even in this case marginal cost never becomes negative. Why? Three Cases of Marginal Cost Functions Case A Decreasing Returns to Scale Case B Constant Returns to Scale Case C Increasing Returns to Scale Marginal cost is above average cost Marginal cost and average cost are equal Marginal cost is below average cost
  • 6. 6 As you will note, I have drawn marginal cost curves that have constant slope. This need not be the case, as we will see in the case of the U-shaped average cost curve. The U-Shaped Average Cost Curve As a practical matter, most economists believe that the typical competitive firm is characterized by a U-shaped average cost curve, where average cost initially falls as a function of the level of output, reaches a minimum and then begin to rise. At the minimum level of AC, MC = AC. At the minimum AC, the slope of the AC curve is zero, which is sufficient to prove that MC = AC. Finally note that the MC cost curve must cut the AC curve from below. Thus we may draw the average cost curve and the marginal cost curve. The U-Shaped Average Cost Curve Here average cost first falls, and then rises. As you can see the marginal cost curve "cuts" the average cost curve at the minimum average cost. Note that I have drawn the MC curve so that it is initially falling. This need not be the case, and we have no special interest in this issue. Fixed and Variable Cost It is sometimes useful to divide the firm’s costs into fixed and variable components. Fixed costs, FC, are the costs the firm would incur if it had no output. That is, FC = C(0). Variable costs are those that vary with output. They may either be defined as the difference between total and fixed costs, VC(q) = C(q) - C(0). It should be obvious that what is defined as “fixed” and “variable” depends on what time period we are talking about. In the long run, there truly are no fixed costs, but in the short run, there may well be. Here is a relation between the average total cost and average variable cost for a U-shaped average cost curve. As you will note
  • 7. 7  The marginal cost curve cuts the ATC and the AVC costs at their minimum  The minimum of AVC occurs at a lower level of output that the minimum of the ATC cost curve  Average Variable Cost is not equal to marginal cost  Average Variable Cost is less than average cost  As output grows infinitely large, AVC approaches ATC Average Variable Cost and Average Total Cost for the U- Shaped Average Cost Curve Average fixed cost is continually declining, and the minimum of AVC occurs at a lower level of output that the minimum of ATC. MC cuts both the ATC and AVC curve at their respective minimum. Other Factors Affecting Cost We originally wrote the cost function as C(q,r,w) to indicate that cost was affected by things other than output. Here are some trick questions: First Trick Question  Acme Widgets’ costs are now $100, of which $50 represents factor payments to workers and $50 represents payments to capital. (To make life easier, assume that Acme Widgets leases all plant and equipment.). Now suppose that wage rates are increase by 100%. Will total costs go from $100 to $150 Clearly not. If Acme continued to use the same amounts of capital and labor, the answer would be yes. But, given the new slope of the isocost lines (the situation is illustrated in Figure 8-8) Acme will substitute capital for labor and reduce the cost increase to less than 50%.
  • 8. 8 Isocost Lines with a Factor Price Shift A change in factor prices causes isocost lines to rotate. As this graph shows,, the minimum cost of producing Qo units is not 50% higher. Rather than stay at (Ko, Lo), the firm will move to another point such as (K1, L1) on an isocost line below C=$150. Second Trick Question  Is it possible that the higher price of labor will lead Acme to lower total costs for the given level of output? This is a good trick question for examinations, and sometimes people do claim that higher factor payments can lead to lower costs. But this is nonsense. Suppose, for instance, that Acme could find a new solution involving $60 of capital payments and $30 of labor costs (at the new wage rate). At the old wage rate, costs would only have been $80 = $60 + $20, which would violate our assumption that $100 represented the least cost. Any manager claiming that higher wager rates lead to lower costs is simply admitting that he wasn’t doing his job in the first place. Third Trick Question  Does an increase in total cost mean that average cost has gone up, and that marginal cost has gone up? Why a Rise in Total Cost Doesn't Mean a Rise in Marginal Cost
  • 9. 9 Here, a rise in total cost leads to a different production technology with the lower marginal cost. Another trick question. A possible illustration of why not is given. The average cost curve shifts up and to the right from AC to AC*, and the marginal cost curve shifts from MC to MC*. So MC has declined. The intuition behind this is quite simple. A rise in labor cost, say, may lead a firm to purchase a new piece of capital. Thus the average cost will rise (see the previous example to see why it cannot fall), but, equipped with the new machine, marginal cost may well be less. Fourth Trick Question  Does technological change reduce costs? We normally mean by technological change the ability to get more output from a given combination of labor and capital. In our terms, technological change shifts the isoquants out. And, if all of the isoquant (or at least the portion we are currently using) is shifted out, then technological change does reduce costs. But some caveats are in order. Don’t confuse changes in technology with changes in technique. In the example given above, a 50% increase in wage rates leads to a change in technique. There are always several different ways of achieving the same objective, using what we call techniques. We all know how to mow a lawn by hand, or with a standard lawn mower, or with one of the larger mowers that commercial services use. Switching from one to another is switching from one technique to another. The switch in technology comes when a new type of mowing machine is invented. For reasons we will get to later, it is important to distinguish between firm specific technologies and industry technologies. A firm specific technology is one that only one firm can use, protected either by something like trade secrets or patent rights, while industry technology represents something that affects all firms in the industry. An example: when Apple developed the Macintosh, it patented its software, and thus froze out competitors. When IBM came out with the PC in the 1980’s it allowed for open architecture, including the DOS system. Other firms quickly adopted DOS, and any advantage that IBM had quickly disappeared.
  • 10. 10 Technological change occurs gradually. Two examples will make the point. The original IBM PC, not yet 15 years old, had 64 k of memory, a 64k floppy and an 8086 chip. The current system is more likely to use 250 times as much memory, a floppy disk 20 times as large (not to speak of hard disks), and a Pentium chip, with many times the power. Yet this change occurred gradually, and in fact represented a continuation of the computer revolution of the last 40 years. Fifth Trick Question  Last year, Acme Widgets produced widgets at $5 each. This year the plant manager reports that he can cut production cost to $4 each. Does this mean he simply was not doing his job last year? While it is always possible that the manager was not doing his job last year, it may also mean something more complicated. In World War II, the Pentagon contracted large production runs of planes, tanks and the like to specific plants. They discovered over time that the cost of producing a plane or tank at a specific plant declined, because, over time, the plant learned all sorts of production tricks. Economists and production specialists labeled this phenomenon as the learning curve, reflecting the commonsense notion of learning by doing. That is, the more we do of something, the better we get at it. Thus a firm's cost function might be a function C(qt, Qt) the number of units it produces this period, qt, as well as the cumulative number of units it has produced, Qt. Thus over time, the firm's average cost function shifts down because of learning by doing. Figure 8-10 shows how the production function could shift. Imagine a firm whose cost function is Ct = ctqt That is, at any time, the marginal cost of producing the product is constant. However, over time, marginal cost declines as a function of Qt, the cumulative number of units produced. Learning by Doing: How the Cost Function Shifts Imagine a firm whose cost function is Ct = ctqt, but where ct is a declining function of the cumulative number of units produced. ct might look like this. Sixth Trick Question  Last year, Acme Widgets produced widgets for $5 each. This year Acme's Costs will be $4. A new competitor, Wonder Widgets, figures that it can produce widgets for $4.50 each. Does
  • 11. 11 this mean that Acme was inefficient? Does it mean that Wonder Widgets stole trade secrets from Acme? Again, Acme may have been inefficient, and Wonder Widgets may have stolen trade secrets from Acme. One can learn a lot by simply observing competitor. If Wonder Widgets simply purchases a widget from Acme, and turns it over to its production specialists for study, there will be a chorus of "So that is what they do!" It is, if you will, just like looking at instructor's old exams. The knowledge will pay off. In fact, there is a general principle: much technological change can confer only a temporary advantage on its developer. We rightly have patent laws to protect new technologies, for else there would be little reason to develop new technology. But the “high tech” firms clearly recognize that the result of new technology hitting the market is for it to be copied, sometimes illegally, but often legally. Thus a high tech firm cannot rest on its laurels, but must continually innovate to keep a cost advantage. Applications of Cost Functions to Some Problems of the Firm We can show how some of this material applies by considering two problems that a firm faces in making production decisions. Allocating output between two different plants The first involves allocating output between two different plants. Suppose a manufacturer has two plants, "A" and "B". The average and marginal cost functions for the two plants are given in Figure 8-11. As you can see, plant "A" has a higher average cost and a higher marginal cost for each and every level of output than plant "B". While this makes for a nice graph, it is not relevant for management decision making. Marginal and Average Cost for Two Different Plants The example is constructed so that plant "A" has a higher marginal and average cost than plant "B" for every level of output. While this makes for a nice graph, it is irrelevant for decision making.
  • 12. 12 To see why, suppose management is considering producing q* units of output from the two plants. Then it wants to find the allocation of output between the two plants that minimizes total cost of production. Here, the only cost that is relevant is the marginal cost, and the least cost solution is achieved when the marginal cost of each plant is equal. Even though "B" appears to be a more efficient plant, it still pays to allocate some of its production to other the older plant. The graphical solution is shown. Here, the marginal cost of plant "A" is measured from the left- hand side, while the marginal cost of plant "B" is measured from the right hand side. As you can see the two marginal costs are equated when qA is produced at plant "A" and qB = q*-qA is produced at plant "B". Any other point would involve higher cost. Allocating Production Between Two Plants The least cost solution requires that the marginal cost of operation be the same. If the firm is going to produce q* units of output, then optimization occurs at qA. Allocating output between a new type of plant and old plants To see a similar problem, suppose a firm has several plants of type "A" such as illustrated in Figure 8-13. It now becomes possible to build a new type of plant, type "B". As you can see, type B represents a technological innovation, representing lower cost. What should the firm do? (The first thing to recognize is that long run marginal cost is now given by the minimum average cost of plant "B". The firm can build as many of those as it wishes, and operate them at the minimum of the LRAC. Marginal and Average Cost for Two Different Plants
  • 13. 13 A firm is operating a number of plants of type "A". and it now becomes possible to build new, more efficient plants of type "B". This does not mean the firm should shut down its existing plants, merely change the scale of operation. The existing plants should not begin producing qA units of output. That does not mean that it should junk its existing plants. It should continue to operate them where the marginal cost equals the new long run marginal cost. Choosing Plant Size Now consider a different problem. A firm is considering building one of three different plants, whose average costs are as depicted in Figure 8-14. Its long run average cost curve is then a peculiar scallop-shaped figure, representing the minimum of each of these average cost curves. Long Run Average Cost when Different Sized plants are possible A firm can choose between three different plants. Its long run average cost curve is now the scallop-shaped figure, the minimum of the average cost for each of the three plants.
  • 14. 14 It is also possible to extend this analysis to the case of many different sized plants, so that the firm can select from a continuum of plant sizes. While, this discussion is much beloved by professors of economics, we will not go into it here.1 Cost functions In talking about cost functions, we have presupposed a simple cost function C = C(q). While the precise definition of the cost function will depend on the exact nature of the firm's production function, we often illustrate the properties of a cost function with one of two simple standard functions: The Linear Cost Function C = a + b q The Quadratic Cost Function C = a + b q + c q2 For example, the cost function C = 3+ 5q is a linear cost function, while C = 4 + 5q + q2 is a quadratic cost function. The difference between the two functions is straightforward. The first cost function simply contains q, while the second term contains q2 . Let us illustrate some of our basic notions using these cost functions. Fixed Cost Fixed cost is, quite simply the costs when q = 0. It is a simple matter to show that, in the case of both our linear and quadratic cost functions, the first term, a, represents fixed cost. Variable Cost Variable cost is the cost varying with output, or, if you will, total cost less fixed cost. In the case of the linear cost function, variable cost will be the term bq; in the case of the quadratic cost function, variable cost will be bq + cq2 . Average Cost Average cost is total cost divided by quantity, or C(q)/q. In the case of the linear cost function, average cost will be a/q + b. In the case of the quadratic cost function, average cost will be 1 Jacob Viner, who originally did the work, was then at the University of Chicago and later at Princeton University. Viner stumbled on this discussion by accident. He did it wrong, and only discovered his error when one of his Ph.D. students, assigned the task of drafting the graphs reported that he could not draw them the way Viner wanted them. For this, Viner got an important article published and the Ph.D. student got a footnote. It should serve as a reminder to readers of these notes to check the logic carefully behind each graph.
  • 15. 15 a/q + b + cq. We could also compute average fixed cost and average variable cost. Marginal Cost Marginal cost is simply the incremental cost of producing an additional unit of the product. The idea is the incremental cost C, associated with producing an incremental unit of output, Q. When we are dealing with simple production functions such as linear or quadratic functions, we customarily compute the marginal cost by taking the derivative of the cost function. That is In words, marginal cost is the derivative of the cost function with respect to output. For those rusty on elementary differential calculus, remember that, in the case of our linear cost function C'(q) = b and in the case of the quadratic cost function C'(q)= b + 2cq Two Problems Here are two simple exercises. One is worked, and one is left for you to do on your own. Suppose a firm has a cost function C = 10 +20q + 4q2 .  Compute total cost, total variable cost, total fixed cost, average cost, average variable cost, average fixed cost, and marginal cost when q=10.  Find the value of q at which MC = AC.  What level of output minimizes AC?
  • 16. 16  At what level of output is marginal cost equal 60? Answers  Total cost is 10 + 20 (10) + 4(10)2 = 610. Total variable cost is the last two terms, or 600. Average cost is 10. To compute average cost, average variable cost, and average foxed cost, just divide by 10 to get 61,60, and 1 respectively. Marginal cost is given by 20 + 8q = 100 when q = 10.  Average cost is 10/q + 20 + 4q. We want to find the value at which 10/q + 20 + 4q = 20 + 8q. Simplifying, we get that 10/q = 4q and we can solve that equation to get q2 = 2.5, or q = 1.58  We know that MC = AC at the minimum of the AC function. Thus, from the answer above, we know that the minimum occurs at 1.58.  Recall that MC = 20 + 8q. That equals 60 when q = 5. A Second Problem Suppose the cost function is C = 5+ 10q2 . Compute the same answers asked for above. 1. A person managing dry cleaning store for $30,000 per year decides to open a dry cleaning store. The revenues of the store during the first year of operation are $100,000 and the expenses are $35,000 for salaries, $10,000 for supplies, $8,000 for rent, $2,000 for utilities, and $5,000 for interest on a bank loan. Calculate: a. the explicit cost Explicit costs = salaries + supplies + rent + utilities + interest on the bank loan = 35000 + 10000 + 8000 + 2000 + 5000 = $60000. b. the implicit costs Implicit costs = entrepreneur forgone salary = $30000. c. the accounting profit Accounting profit = TR - explicit costs = 100000 - 60000 = $40000 d. the economic profit Economic profit = TR - explicit costs - implicit costs = 100000 - 60000 - 30000 = $10000 e. Indicate whether the person should open the dry cleaning store Since the person would earn an economic profit of $10000 per year, he or she should open the dry cleaning store: positive economic profits.
  • 17. 17 2. Answer the following questions: a. What is the slope of the line that goes through (2, 5), (8, 2)? m = (2 - 5) / (8 - 2) = - 3 / 6 = - 1 / 2 slope = -0.5 b. What is the slope of the line for which an equation is: 6x + 3y - 12 = 0 3y = 12 - 6x y = 4 - 2x slope = -2 c. Is the following equation an equation for a demand or for a supply curve? 2q + 6p - 8 = 0 6p = 8 - 2q p = 4/3 -(1 / 3)q This is a demand curve because the slope is negative. 3. You are given the Total Cost function TC = (1/3)Q^3 - 8.5Q^2 +60Q+27 a. Derive the AC and MC functions AC = TCQ = (1/3)Q^2 - 8.5Q + 60 + 27/Q MC = dTR/dQ = Q^2 - 17Q +60 b. Explain the (graphical, i.e. in terms of slopes) relationship between TC and MC MC is the slope of TC. c. Determine the level of output at which the total cost function is minimized and the level of total cost (Hint: You will need to check the second derivative). We need to solve: Q^2- 17Q + 60 = 0, (Q - 12)*(Q - 5) = 0, so the optimum are Q= 5 and 12. Checking the second derivative to see which one of these is a minimum, dMC / dQ = 2Q - 17 2(5) - 17 < 0, thus Q = 5 corresponds to a maximum. 2(12) - 17 > 0, thus, Q = 12 corresponds to a minimum. At Q = 12, TC = (1 /3)*123 - 8.5*122 + 60*12 + 27 = 99. 4. A market demand is such that if price is $10 per unit, the quantity demanded is 100. For each $1 increase in price, the quantity demanded decreases by 20. The quantity supplied is zero until the price reaches $5. Above that price, the quantity supplied increases by 10 for each $1 increase in price. a. Determine the equation of the supply and demand curve. First, one needs two data points. An example is: P = 10, Q = 100; P = 11, Q = 80. Then, we can calculate the slope: Slope = (10 - 11) / (100 - 80) = -0.05 = a. Using (Q = 100, P = 10), we have P = b - 0.05Q, where b is the vertical intercept. Solving for b yields b = 10 + 0.05*100 = 15. The equation of the demand curve is therefore P = 15 - 0.05Q. Now we can do the same thing for the supply: The 2 data points can be for example (Q = 0, P = 5) and (Q = 10, P = 6). Slope = (6- 5) / (10 - 0) = 0.1. We know that the vertical intercept is 5 (see above), thus, the equation of the supply curve is P = 5 + 0.1Q. b. What are the demand and supply functions? For the demand: 0.05Q = 15 - P, so Q = 300 - 20P.
  • 18. 18 Similarly for the supply function, inverting the equation of the supply curve yields: Q = -50 + 10P. c. What is the equilibrium price and quantity? Setting demand = supply yields: -50 + 10P = 300 - 20P, 350 = 30P, P = 350 / 30 = $11.67 Plugging in the demand or supply function to get quantities yields: Q = Q = -50 + 10(11.67) = 66.67. 5. Using the demand function Q = 300 - 10P (1) a. Determine the equation of the total revenue (TR), average revenue (AR) and marginal revenue (MR). TR = PQ. In order to calculate it, one needs to invert the demand function so that we can find the demand curve equation: 10P = 300 - Q, P = 30 - 0.1Q. Now, if we multiply both side of the demand curve equation by Q, we will have an expression for total revenue: TR = PQ = (30 - 0.1Q)*Q = 30Q - 0.1Q2 Average revenue is defined as TR / Q: AR = (30Q - 0.1Q2 ) / Q = 30 - 0.1Q Marginal revenue is defined as the first derivative of total revenue: MR = dTR / dQ = 30 - 0.2Q b.c. see class notes/ not included d. Determine mathematically at what quantity is total revenue maximized. Check that you have maximized not minimized total revenue. In order to maximize total revenue, one needs to set the first derivative of the total revenue function (the marginal revenue function) equal to 0: 30 - 0.2Q = 0, 30 = 0.2Q, Q = 30 / 0.2 = 150. At quantities of 150, total revenue is optimized. In order to know whether we have a maximum or a minimum, one needs to check the second derivative: d2TR / dQ2 = dMR / dQ = -0.2. Since -0.2 < 0, we conclude that we have maximized not minimized total revenue at Q = 150. SUNK COST Sunk costs are retrospective costs that cannot be recovered, and are therefore irrelevant to future investment decisions in the project which incurs them. CHECKPOINTS o Only prospective costs should impact an investment decision. Therefore, sunk costs are not to be considered when deciding whether to undertake a project. o A sunk cost is distinct from an economic loss. A loss may be caused by a sunk cost, however. o Sunk costs are irrecoverable.
  • 19. 19 Sunk Costs Examples Let’s say a company spent $5 million building an airplane. Before the plane is complete, the managers learn that it is obsolete and no airline will buy it. The market has evolved and now the airlines want a different type of plane. The company can finish the obsolete plane for another $1 million, or it can start over and build the new type of plane for $3 million. What should the managers decide? Should they spend that last $1 million to finish up the plane that’s almost done, or should they spend the $3 million to build the new plane? At first glance, you may think the company should just finish the old plane. It’s only another million bucks and they already spent $5 million. But in reality, the five million is irrelevant. It is a sunk cost. The only relevant cost is the $3 million dollars. The managers should consider whether or not to spend $3 million on the new plane, and nothing regarding the old plane should affect the decision. DIFFERENCE BETWEEN SUNK COST AND ECONOMIC LOSS The sunk cost is distinct from economic loss. For example, when a car is purchased, it can subsequently be resold; however, it will probably not be resold for the original purchase price. The economic loss is the difference between these values (including transaction costs). The sum originally paid should not affect any rational future decision-making about the car, regardless of the resale value. If the owner can derive more value from selling the car than not selling it, then it should be sold, regardless of the price paid. In this sense, the sunk cost is not a precise quantity, but an economic term for a sum paid in the past, which is no longer relevant to decisions about the future. The sunk cost may be used to refer to the original cost or the expected economic loss. It may also be used as shorthand for an error in analysis due to the sunk cost fallacy, irrational decision-making or, most simply, as irrelevant data. Sunk Costs Fallacy The sunk cost fallacy is when someone considers a sunk cost in a decision and subsequently makes a poor decision. An example of the sunk cost fallacy is paying for a movie ticket, finding out the movie is terrible, and staying to watch anyway just to get your money’s worth. When you find out the movie is terrible, you should make a decision whether to sit through the bad movie or to do something more meaningful with your time – the price you paid for the ticket should not affect your decision. The ticket price is a sunk cost. Another example of the sunk cost fallacy is paying for an all-you-can-eat buffet, eating until you’re full, and then going back for more just to get your money’s worth. When you are full, you should decide
  • 20. 20 whether you want to eat more or to stop eating – the fact that you paid for unlimited food should not affect your decision. The price of the buffet is a sunk cost. COST CURVES
  • 21. 21
  • 22. 22 EXPANSION PATH The change in the optimal input bundle when output changes depends on the nature of the production function. The path of all optimal input bundles as output increases is called the output expansion path. The blue line in the following figure is an example of an output expansion path. In this example, as output increases initially more of both inputs are used. Then, between the second and third isocost lines the amount of input 2 used starts to decline. If the optimal amount of an input increases with output then the input is called normal, while if the amount used decreases then the input is called inferior. Example: a production function with fixed proportions Consider the production function F (z1, z2) = min{z1, z2}. Given the shape of its isoquants, the output expansion path of this production function is a ray from the origin, as in the following figure. For any input prices, the firm uses y units of each input to produce y units of output (see its conditional input demands), so that its output expansion path is the line z2 = z1.
  • 23. 23 Example: a production function with fixed proportions Consider the production function F (z1, z2) = min{z1/2, z2}. Given the shape of its isoquants, the output expansion path of this production function is a ray from the origin, as in the following figure. For any input prices, the firm uses 2y units of input 1 and y units of input 2 to produce y units of output (see its conditional input demands), so that its output expansion path is the line z2 = z1/2. Example: a general production function with fixed proportions A general production function with fixed proportions takes the form F (z1, z2) = min{az1, bz2} for some constants a and b. Given the shape of its isoquants, the output expansion path of this production function is, as in the previous case, a ray from the origin. For any input prices, the firm uses y/a units of input 1 and y/b units of input 2 to produce y units of output (see its conditional input demands), so that its output expansion path is the line z2 = (a/b)z1.
  • 24. 24 Example: a production function in which the inputs are perfect substitutes Consider the production function F (z1, z2) = z1 + z2, in which the inputs are perfect substitutes. Given the shape of its isoquants, its output expansion path is  the z2 axis if w1 > w2 (if the price of input 1 exceeds that of input 2 then the firm uses none of input 1)  the z1 axis if w1 < w2 (if the price of input 2 exceeds that of input 1 then the firm uses none of input 2)  the set of all pairs (z1, z2) if w1 = w2 (if the prices of the inputs are the same then every combination of inputs is optimal). [That is, in this case there is not a single output expansion path.]
  • 25. 25 Example: a general production function in which the inputs are perfect substitutes The general form of a production function in which the inputs are perfect substitutes is F (z1, z2) = az1 + bz2, for some constants a and b. Given the shape of its isoquants, its output expansion path is  the z2 axis (the firm uses none of input 1) if w1 > (a/b)w2  the z1 axis (the firm uses none of input 2) if w1 < (a/b)w2  the set of all pairs (z1, z2) (every combination of inputs is optimal) if w1 = (a/b)w2. [That is, in this case there is not a single output expansion path.] Example: a Cobb-Douglas production function Consider the Cobb-Douglas production function F (z1, z2) = z1 1/2 z2 1/2 . The conditional input demand functions for this production function are z1 = y(w2/w1)1/2 and z2 = y(w1/w2)1/2 . Thus the output expansion path satisfies z2/z1 = w1/w2, or z2 = (w1/w2)z1. As in all the previous examples, the output expansion path is thus a ray from the origin. Long run and short run cost functions In the long run, the firm can vary all its inputs. In the short run, some of these inputs are fixed. Since the firm is constrained in the short run, and not constrained in the long run, the long run cost TC(y) of producing any given output y is no greater than the short run cost STC(y) of producing that output: TC(y) STC(y) for all y. Now consider the case in which in the short run exactly one of the firm's inputs is fixed. For concreteness, suppose that the firm uses two inputs, and the amount of input 2 is fixed at k. For many (but not all) production functions, there is some level of output, say y0, such that the firm would choose to use k units of input 2 to produce y0, even if it were free to choose any amount it wanted. In such a case, for this level of output the short run total cost when the firm is constrained to use k units of input 2 is equal to the long run total cost: STCk(y0) = TC(y0). We generally assume that for any level at which input 2 is fixed, there is some level of output for which that amount of input 2 is appropriate, so that for any value of k, TC(y) = STCk(y) for some y. (There are production functions for which this relation is not true, however: see the example of a production function in which the inputs are perfect substitutes.)
  • 26. 26 For a total cost function with the typical shape, the following figure shows the relations between STC and TC. Examples of long run and short run cost functions Long run and short run average cost functions Given the relation between the short and long run total costs, the short and long run average and marginal cost functions have the forms shown in the following figure. Note:  The SMC goes through the minimum of the SAC and the LMC goes through the minimum of the LAC.
  • 27. 27  When SAC = LAC we must have SMC = LMC (since slopes of total cost functions are the same there). In the case that the production function has CRTS, the LAC is horizontal, as in the following figure. Derivation of Long-Run Marginal Cost Curve The Derivation of Long-Run Marginal Cost Curve! Since marginal cost curve is important both from the viewpoint of the short run and the long run, it will be useful to know how the long-run marginal cost curve is derived. The long-run marginal cost curve can be directly derived from the long-run total cost curve, since the long-run marginal cost at a level of output is given by the slope of the total cost curve at the point corresponding to that level of output. Besides, the long-ran marginal cost curve can be derived from the long-run average cost curve, because the long-ran marginal cost curve is related to the long-run average cost curve in the same way as the short-ran marginal cost curve is related to short-run average cost curve. In Fig. 19.12, it is depicted that how the long-run marginal cost curve LMC is derived from a long-run average cost curve LAC enveloping a family of short-run average and marginal cost curves.
  • 28. 28 If the output OA is too produced in the long ran, then it must be produced on the long-run average cost curve LAC at point H which is a tangency point with the short-run average cost curve SAC1. Thus, when output OA is to be produced in the long run, it will be produced with the plant corresponding to the short- run average cost curve SAC1 and the short-run marginal cost curve SMC1. Corresponding to the tangency point H between the short-run average cost curve SAC1 and the long-run average cost curve LAC, there is a point N on the short run marginal cost curve SMC. This means that the production of output OA in the long run involves the marginal cost AN. Therefore point N must lie on the long-run marginal cost curve corresponding to output OA. If output OB is to be produced in the long run, it will be produced at point Q which is the tangency point between LAC and SAC2. Q is also the point on the short-run marginal cost curve SMC2, corresponding to output OB. (Q is the common point between SAC2 and SMC2 because Q is the minimum point of SAC2, at which the SMC2, cuts it from below). Thus Q must also lie on the long-run marginal cost curve corresponding to output OB. Similarly, if output OC is to be produced in the long run, it will be produced at point M which is the tangency point between LAC and SAC3 Corresponding to point M, the relevant point on the SMC3 is K which means that the long-run marginal cost of producing OC is CK. Thus point K must lie on the long-run marginal cost curve corresponding to output OC. By connecting points N, Q and K we obtain the long-run marginal cost curve LMC. It will be seen from Fig. 19.12 that the long-run marginal cost curves is flatter than the short-run marginal cost curves. It should also be remembered that the relationship between the long-run marginal cost curve LMC and the long-run average cost curve LAC is the same as that between the short-run marginal cost curve and the short -run average cost curve. Thus, when the long-run marginal cost curve LMC lies below the long-run average cost curve, the latter will be falling, and when the long-run marginal cost curve lies above the long-run average cost, the latter will be rising. When the long- run marginal cost is equal to the long- run average cost, the latter will be neither rising nor falling. Relationship of LAC and LMC with SAC and SMC:
  • 29. 29 It is important to note that LAC and SAC curves are related in an important way with SMC and LMC curves. This relationship shows, as will be seen from Fig. 19.13, that at the level of output at which a particular SAC curve is tangent to the LAC curve, the corresponding SMC curve intersects the LMC curve. This relationship can be proved using a short-run total cost curve and the long run total cost curve and this has been done in Figure 19.13 where a short-run total cost curve STC and the long-run total cost curve LTC are drawn. It will be seen from Figure 19.13 that long-run total cost curve LTC lies below the short-run total cost curve STC at all levels of output except at output OA at which the two curves are tangent. This means that L4C is less than SAC at all levels of output other than OA. As will be seen from the bottom of panel figure 19.13 that long-run average cost LAC will be equal to the short-run average cost SAC at output OA at which LTC curve is tangent to the STC curve. But the long- run marginal cost LMC must also be equal to short-run marginal cost SMC at output OA i.e. the tangency point P. This is because marginal cost is given by the slope of the total cost curve at any point, and the LTC curve and STC curve have the same slope at the tangency point P. It will be seen from the bottom panel of Fig. 19.13 that at output level OA, where the SAC is equal to the LAC, SMC is also equal to the LMC.
  • 30. 30 Economies of Scope WRITE A COMMENT Economies of scope are cost advantages that result when firms provide a variety of products rather than specializing in the production or delivery of a single product or service. Economies of scope also exist if a firm can produce a given level of output of each product line more cheaply than a combination of separate firms, each producing a single product at the given output level. Economies of scope can arise from the sharing or joint utilization of inputs and lead to reductions in unit costs. Scope economies are frequently documented in the business literature and have been found to exist in countries, electronic-based B2B (business-to-business) providers, home healthcare, banking, publishing, distribution, and telecommunications. METHODS OF ACHIEVING ECONOMIES OF SCOPE Flexible Manufacturing The use of flexible processes and flexible manufacturing systems has resulted in economies of scope because these systems allow quick, low-cost switching of one product line to another. If a producer can manufacture multiple products with the same equipment and if the equipment allows the flexibility to change as market demands change, the manufacturer can add a variety of new products to their current line. The scope of products increases, offering a barrier to entry for new firms and a competitive synergy for the firm itself. Related Diversification Economies of scope often result from a related diversification strategy and may even be termed "economies of diversification." This strategy is made operational when a firm builds upon or extends existing capabilities, resources, or areas of expertise for greater competitiveness. According to Hill, Ireland, and Hoskisson in their best selling strategic management textbook, Strategic Management: Competitiveness and Globalization, firms select related diversification as their corporate-level strategy in an attempt to exploit economies of scope between their various business units. Cost-savings result when a business transfers expertise in one business to a new business. The businesses can share operational skills and know-how in manufacturing or even share plant facilities, equipment, or other existing assets. They may also share intangible assets like expertise or a corporate core competence. Such sharing of activities is common and is a way to maximize limited constraints. As an example, Kleenex Corporation manufactures a number of paper products for a variety of end users, including products targeted specifically for hospitals and health care providers, infants, children, families, and women. Their brands include Kleenex, Viva, Scott, and Cottonelle napkins, paper towels, and facial tissues; Depends and Poise incontinence products; Huggies diapers and wipes; Pull-Ups, Goodnites, and Little Swimmers infant products; Kotex, New Freedom, Litedays, and Security feminine hygiene products; and a number of products for surgical use, infection control, and patient care. All of these product lines utilize similar raw material inputs and/or manufacturing processes as well as distribution and logistics channels.
  • 31. 31 Mergers The merger wave that swept the United States in the late 1990s and early 2000s is, in part, an attempt to create scope economies. Mergers may be undertaken for any number of reasons. "As a rule of thumb," explained Rob Preston in an article about the trouble with mergers, "'scope' acquisitions—moves that enhance or extend a vendor's product portfolio—succeed more often than those undertaken to increase size and consolidate costs." Pharmaceutical companies, for example, frequently combine forces to share research and development expenses and bring new products to market. Research has shown that firms involved in drug discovery realize economies of scope by sustaining diverse portfolios of research projects that capture both internal and external knowledge spillovers. Linked Supply Chains Today's linked supply chains among raw material suppliers, other vendors, manufacturers, wholesalers, distributors, retailers, and consumers often bring about economies of scope. Integrating a vertical supply chain results in productivity gains, waste reduction, and cost improvements. These improvements, which arise from the ability to eliminate costs by operating two or more businesses under the same corporate umbrella, exist whenever it is less costly for two or more businesses to operate under centralized management than to function independently. The opportunity to gain cost savings can arise from interrelationships anywhere along a value chain. As firms become linked in supply chains, particularly as part of the new information economy, there is a growing potential for economies of scope. Scope economies can increase a firm's value and lead to increases in performance and higher returns to shareholders. Building economies of scope can also help a firm to reduce the risks inherent in producing a single product or providing a service to a single industry.