SlideShare a Scribd company logo
1 of 53
AEB 2451: Economics of Resource Use Lecturer: Misti Sharp
1
Assignment 10: Common Pool Resources
Instructions: You may work in groups but you must turn in your
own work! Indicate on the front page who you worked
with (max 3 people). An electronic copy must be submitted
online before midnight on Friday. Show all work so that
partial credit may be given. This homework is worth 15 points
total.
1) Read about the Atlantic Cod and the human “Tragedy of the
Commons” article:
http://www.wbur.org/cognoscenti/2014/12/03/overfishing-
georges-bank-david-ropeik and reflect on
why, economically, a fisherman like Tony could earn so much
money without a degree “back in the
day.” Were the Cod fishermen of years passed truly taking into
account the full opportunity cost when
they were behaving as they were? (3 points)
2) Suppose that the total benefit and total cost for a cod
fisherman in the 1970s was as given in the table
below where one boat could garner $9,000 in total fish revenue
and $5,000 in total costs. Use this
information to answer the next 3 questions.
a. Complete the following table rounding to 1 decimal if
necessary (3 points):
# of
Boats
Total
Benefit
(000s)
Total
Costs
(000s)
Average
Benefit
Marginal
Benefit
Marginal
cost
1 9 5
2 17 10
3 24 15
4 30 20
5 35 25
6 39 30
7 41 35
8 43 40
9 44 45
10 44 50
b. If the fisher were to have accepted the scientific evidence
instead of fighting it and stopped
fishing at the economically efficient level, how many boats
would have been released into the
Gulf of Maine? (3 points)
c. Given that the cod fishery was subject to tragedy, how many
boats were likely released into the
Gulf of Maine? (3 points)
3) Read the following article and discuss how we are responding
to the lack of Cod in the US:
https://www.usnews.com/news/best-states/maine/articles/2017-
03-24/maines-cod-fishermen-have-
worst-year-in-history In the “Global Scarcity” part of the
course, we talked about becoming self-
sufficient in food production. Would those tactics work for this
fishery resource? Why or why not? (3
points)
AEB 2451: Economics of Resource Use Lecturer: Misti Sharp
2
4) Read the attached article by Lynne and Burkhart (1990) about
Florida Water Institutions. Discuss how
water is managed in Florida. From a neoclassical theory
perspective, does it appear as if it is possible to
allocate water efficiently in Florida? What is required for
efficient allocation using a neoinstitutional
approach? Based on the discussion provided by the article, are
you surprised that there have been “water
wars” in Florida in recent years? Answer all questions fully for
full credit. (3 points)
The Evolution of Water Institutions in Florida: A
Neoinstitutionalist Perspective
Author(s): Gary D. Lynne and Jeffrey Burkhardt
Source: Journal of Economic Issues, Vol. 24, No. 4 (Dec.,
1990), pp. 1059-1077
Published by: Taylor & Francis, Ltd.
Stable URL: https://www.jstor.org/stable/4226346
Accessed: 05-11-2018 16:00 UTC
JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars,
researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide
range of content in a trusted digital archive. We use information
technology and tools to increase productivity and
facilitate new forms of scholarship. For more information about
JSTOR, please contact [email protected]
Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the
Terms & Conditions of Use, available at
https://about.jstor.org/terms
Taylor & Francis, Ltd. is collaborating with JSTOR to digitize,
preserve and extend access to
Journal of Economic Issues
This content downloaded from 128.227.197.233 on Mon, 05
Nov 2018 16:00:57 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
JeI JOURNAL OF ECONOMIC ISSUES
Vol. XXIV No. 4 December 1990
The Evolution of Water Institutions in Florida:
A Neoinstitutionalist Perspective
Gary D. Lynne
and
Jeffrey Burkhardt
In most areas of the United States, water has not been
considered
tradeable in markets like other basic commodities (food,
clothing, and
shelter). Neoclassical (NC) theorists frequently refer somewhat
dispar-
agingly to this phenomenon as the "water is different
syndrome," and
go on to suggest that the results of the non-market allocation of
water
are less than optimal [see Gardner 1983, p. 85]. Since people
involved
in water institutions are "rent-seekers" [see Gardner 1983, p.
104-5,
1 13; Anderson 1983, Chap. 4]-a description that tends to give
visions
of evil wealth stealers busily creating ways to take or to keep
wealth
from others-society, as a result, has to play a "negative sum
game"
[Anderson 1983, p. 19]. This detracts from the ability of good
wealth
creators to maximize wealth. The NC solution to this problem,
there-
fore, nearly always involves proposing a system of tradeable
water
rights and a market process to replace the administrative
structure that
has evolved in some states. This is the only hope for alleviating
the
"policy drought" [Anderson 1983]. The NC presumption seems
to be
that all conflict arising from scarcity (and from differing
values, beliefs,
The authors are, respectively, Professor ofAgricultural
Economics andAssociate Profes-
sor of Ethics and Public Policy in the Food and Resource
Economics Department at the
University of Florida, Gainesville. They are grateful to Roy R.
Carriker and to anonymous
JEI reviewers for helpful comments. This is Florida
Agricultural Experiment Station Jour-
nal Series No. R-00522.
1059
This content downloaded from 128.227.197.233 on Mon, 05
Nov 2018 16:00:57 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
1060 Gary D. Lynne and Jeffrey Burkhardt
attitudes and behavior) is reduced substantially and sufficiently
when
policy facilitates the efficiency dynamics of markets.
Analysts in the neoinstitutional (NI) tradition do not appear to
find
the political and social reality surrounding water either
surprising or
problematical. For example, Lee Brown et al. [1982, p. 194]
have noted
how finding appropriate western U.S. water institutions has
always in-
volved solving a problem in political economy and not just
finding an
institution that will efficiently generate wealth. Leonard
Shabman and
William E. Cox [1986, p. 134] have argued that economic
efficiency
may not be the main concern or desired goal of Virginia water
institu-
tions. Even if economic efficiency motivated institutional
change, any
move to marketing "should be subjected to a benefit-cost
comparison"
with other processes [Shabman and Cox 1986, p. 165]. Water
markets
would likely be possible only after "protracted political debate"
if ever.
Shabman and Cox note how the Virginia legislature has
consistently
rejected moves toward water marketing [Shabman and Cox,
1986, p.
165]. Regarding rent-seeking, Michael S. McPherson has
argued that
self seeking with respect to resources has cultural and moral
limits, so
that the view that non-market water institutions always reflect
and
serve the interests of wealth stealers may not be defensible
[McPherson
1984, p. 71]. Indeed, water institutions may instead reflect
more fun-
damental social values that may serve to influence and
constrain the
behavior of potential rent-seekers.
This article explores the appropriateness of NI theory for
explaining
the character and evolution of water institutions. The focus of
this anal-
ysis is Florida's efforts over the past two decades to deal with
"the water
problem." Others have used NI theory to analyze water
institutions.
Philip R. Wandschneider found NI theory suitable for
explaining re-
cent institutional water change in the Pacific Northwest:
efficiency gains
were not even the issue; the issue was conflict and who was to
have
access to and control over water [Wandschneider 1986, esp. p.
97].
James A. Swaney used NI theory to improve our understanding
of why
water markets are not found extensively in the arid western
United
States, although he suggests that instituting water markets
could prove
to be a positive change [Swaney 1988]. Swaney suggests,
however, ad-
ministered markets as opposed to the "market system"
suggested in NC
theory [Swaney 1988, pp. 43, 44]. Charles Howe, et al.
advocate the
market system, but they also recognize potential market
shortcomings
[Howe, Schurmeier, and Shaw 1986, p. 440]. An inference
could be
drawn from their analysis that other possible goals for water
policy,
such as equity, fairness, and "socially responsible water
allocation,"
This content downloaded from 128.227.197.233 on Mon, 05
Nov 2018 16:00:57 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
Evolution of Florida Water Institutions 1061
may be better accounted for in NI theory. We hypothesize that
insofar
as NI theory explains the existence and evolution of water
institutions
in Florida, it may also provide some clues as to the likely
future course
of Florida water institutions, in particular, the possible
evolution of wa-
ter markets.
Contrasting Theories of Humans and Society
One of the reasons NI theory better explains the system of
water-
resource allocation in Florida is that NI theory explicitly
addresses the
variety of motives and values that underlies individual and
collective
actions (see Hodgson [1988, p. xvi, 13, 16]). This is in contrast
to NC
theory, which assumes that the main, if not exclusive,
determinant of
individual and collective behavior is utility-maximization. For
indi-
viduals, utility maximizing consists of (1) determining how
much time
and effort will be devoted to obtaining more income, conceived
as the
leisure/work tradeoff [all objectives (values) other than the
ones satis-
fied with money goods are subsumed under "leisure"]; and (2)
purchas-
ing as many market goods as possible with the income (profit,
wealth)
available. As each individual maximizes utility within the
constraints
of her or his own "leisure" (other objectives) choice, resource
con-
straints, and the utility-maximizing behavior of others, a
"social opti-
mum" is assumed to result. We will return to this below.
NI theory assumes that individual (and collective) behavior
results
from a considerably more complex set of factors: an
individual's be-
havior reflects priorities and trade-offs among a large number
of values
and objectives (Wendell Gordon and John Adams [1989, pp.
101-114]
summarize several different views on this matter, pp. 101-114).
Inter-
action occurs within the context of others' similar (or different)
kinds
of trade-priorities and trade-offs. Given this assumption, NI
analysts
attempt to identify the range of underlying values, beliefs, and
attitudes
(and to determine the origin of each) that influence behavior
and do
not subsume all such values and beliefs under the "leisure"
concept. It
might be found, for example, that some individuals
predominately act
to acquire profits (having traded off leisure for money), while
others
do not exhibit profit-maximizing behavior at all [Tool 1986, p.
184].
In NI theory, however, the latter have traded off "other values"
against
profit, not simply leisure. For NI theory, since all actions
reflect both
the values of the individual and her or his cultural context (that
is, oth-
ers' values), explaining behavior is an empirical matter: what
values,
beliefs, and attitudes, are motivating people? In NC theory, to
the con-
This content downloaded from 128.227.197.233 on Mon, 05
Nov 2018 16:00:57 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
1062 Gary D. Lynne and Jeffrey Burkhardt
trary, the maximization view is an untested assumption, or a
method-
ological convenience [Caldwell 1982].
Operationally, NI theory is in this respect consistent with and
in
some respects dependent upon the work of social psychologists
such as
Milton Rokeach [1973] (see also [Hodgson 1988, chaps. 3-6],
in deter-
mining what values people actually hold. Contrary to the NC
maximi-
zation model, Rokeach suggests that there is a multiplicity of
values
that people pursue or use as standards for determining the
means and
ends for behavior [Rokeach 1973, p. 13]; compare Tool [1986,
p. 8].
Rokeach distinguishes between end-state or terminal values,
and func-
tional' values pursued to help in achieving end-state values.
Based
upon extensive empirical work, Rokeach has identified the
following
prevalent end-state or terminal values: a comfortable life, an
exciting
life, a sense of accomplishment, a world of peace, equality,
family secu-
rity, freedom, happiness, inner harmony, mature love, national
secu-
rity, pleasure, salvation, self-respect, social recognition, true
friendship,
and wisdom [Rokeach 1973, p. 28]. Functional values include:
ambi-
tion, broadmindedness, capability, cheerfulness, cleanliness,
courage,
helpfulness, honesty, imaginativeness, independence, as well as
being
intellectual, logical, loving, obedient, polite, responsible, and
self-
controlled. Note that most values cannot generally be
purchased with
more money.
Given different accounts of individual psychology, the
sociology of
NC and NI theory also appears quite different. For NC theory,
the as-
sumption that individuals always maximize income (subject to
internal
and external constraints) leads directly to the position that all
"normal"
interactions among people are market interactions. In theory,
this in-
cludes political interactions [Downs 1957; Buchanan and
Tullock
1967]. Although NC theorists tend to ignore basic institutions-
in-
cluding the market as institution (see Hodgson [1988, Chap.
8])-there
is probably at least implicit agreement among them with
Buchanan's
account2 of how neoclassical assumptions also explain the
origin and
subsequent working of basic institutions in a society.
James M. Buchanan and Gordon Tullock argue that institutions
arise
because of (a) the need for public safety and security, including
enforce-
able contracts; and (b) information and other transaction costs
[Bu-
chanan and Turlock 1967, pp. 47-62; Buchanan 1986, p. 11 1].
Without
a suitable institution (a legal or moral device serving to
stabilize mar-
keting and other human interaction), no productive human
interaction
would occur. Markets, for example, would not function if either
there
are no enforceable contracts or if the participants are not (at
least mini-
This content downloaded from 128.227.197.233 on Mon, 05
Nov 2018 16:00:57 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
Evolution of Florida Water Institutions 1063
mally) capable of obtaining the requisite information to
participate
freely in the market. According to Buchanan, institutions are
therefore
to be understood as having been the result of an agreement that
indi-
viduals entered into at some point (or hypothetically) that
established
the fundamental "constitutional" principles on which
subsequent inter-
actions are to be based. With a "just" background institution in
place,
individuals can simply pursue their self-interest. So long as the
rules
operate, we can ignore the reasons and values that went into the
intitial
agreement.
What Buchanan sees as motivating people to "join" the
contract,
then, is maximization of self-interest [Buchanan 1987, p. 245;
also see
Buchanan and Tullock 1967, pp. 11-15]. The resultant
"constitution"
-although this equally applies to any institution-reflects the
wealth
maximizing goal, although the institutionalizing process
establishes
formal rules for guaranteeing that transactions will be optimal
in this
regard. Whatever other values people have besides
maximization of in-
come-if they have other values-will either be reflected in
market ac-
tivities (that is, prices), or will be taken care of by various
nonmarket
activities (including institutions). Generally, however,
nonmarket ac-
tivities and institutions are inefficient, and hence will not be
"con-
tracted into."
In contrast, NI theory attempts to explain both market and
nonmar-
ket institutions without the a priori assumption that the reason
people
enter into society (or participate in any set of institutions) is to
maximize self-interest. Moreover, NI theory does not assume
that non-
market institutions are generally non-optimal and that markets
are gen-
erally if not always optimal. Indeed, one of the tenets of NI
theory is
that, for a given set of values that individuals hold, sometimes
non-
market institutions are more optimal (value-maximizing or,
possibly,
value-satisficing) than a market institution would be in that
same situ-
ation. In this respect, for NI theory a major focus is on the
"ongoing
process" in the evolution of values and beliefs, and the
institutionaliz-
ing of particular constellations of values, rather than on
behavioral dy-
namics of people within a particular set of market-oriented
institutions
[Gordon and Adams 1989, p. 98]. As technology changes and
people
acquire knowledge about the consequences of past or existing
institu-
tions, technologies, and individual and collective actions,
beliefs and
values change. This feedback can lead to institutional re-design
[Gor-
don and Adams 1989, pp. 17-67].
Some of the values Rokeach and others have identified as
important
in American society appear to be best achieved through or as a
result
This content downloaded from 128.227.197.233 on Mon, 05
Nov 2018 16:00:57 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
1064 Gary D. Lynne and Jeffrey Burkhardt
of maximizing behavior in markets: a comfortable life, family
security,
rational behavior, and others. Other values, however, are
achieved in
or institutionalized in different ways. As Rokeach indicates,
when any
values come to be institutionalized, particular institutions
specialize in
certain subsets of the larger set of "held values" [Rokeach
1979, pp.
50-53].
Another aspect of NI theory is that it accounts for the existence
and
function of a "community of interests," or "moral community,"
to use
Buchanan's [1986] term. Moral community is the idea that in
some sit-
uations or with respect to some issue or problem, individuals
feel them-
selves to be members of an ongoing social enterprise, rather
than
"independent, isolated" maximizing individuals [Buchanan
1986, p.
109]. Mark Sagoff has also noted that rather than perceiving all
situ-
ations as opportunities for maximizing self-interest, individuals
share
a common concern, be it national pride, care for the
environment, pub-
lic health, or any other "social value" [Sagoff 1989] A. Alan
Schmid
also shows how mutual dependence and interdependence among
indi-
viduals underlies this notion of community [Schmid 1987, p.
27]. In-
deed, recognition of interdependence seems the fundamental
feature of
moral community [Dallmayr 1978]. Moral communities can be
both
informally "institutionalized" or formally institutionalized
through a
political process. An important aspect of the latter case is this:
Once a
basic community value is institutionalized, individual and
collective
behavior comes to reflect it (see Gordon and Adams [1989, p.
7]). Moral
community, institutionalized in law or policy, is in this respect
self-
reinforcing.
A moral community can come into existence in any number of
con-
texts and for any number of reasons. Buchanan seems to think
that reli-
gion and a homogeneous cultural tradition underlay the most
pervasive
moral communities [Buchanan 1986, p. 109], although he
admits that
other manifestations or sources of community exist in trade
unions,
firms or social classes. What he does not explain is how a
moral com-
munity-and institutions that reflect it-can come into existence
when
hitherto there was none, and when in fact there had been only
"moral
order"-his term for the social situation wherein self-interested
indi-
viduals interact within the constraints of institutionalized
civility, but
without any common concern or value. An important question
for NI
theory is, however, when and how do widely shared purposes
arise in
the context of institutions and behaviors that aim at the
maximization
of individual wealth? How do institutions thereby change to
reflect and
embody these "new values?"
This content downloaded from 128.227.197.233 on Mon, 05
Nov 2018 16:00:57 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
Evolution of Florida Water Institutions 1065
A number of reasons may explain why a group of individuals
with
different value priorities, different knowledge-levels, different
work and
lifestyles, might coalesce around a particular value or set of
values so
as to constitute a moral community with respect to a specific
issue or
problem. Certainly widespread perception of a "social crisis"
could be
one factor [Burkhardt 1988]. Increased knowledge about a
situation
where there already had been some degree of community would
be an-
other. Deliberate "contracting" for mutual defense or advantage
would
be a third. Strong charismatic leadership that brings about a
coales-
cence of values might be another [Buchholz, 1982]. The point
is that
moral communities can arise, and that institutions that reflect
them
can come to exist-or pass out of existence. Or, perhaps more
relevant
to the discussion below, the institutions can be created to
reflect an
emergent moral community, only to reinforce the notion of
community
and interdependence in the ongoing process of administering
the value-
mandate of the initial institutionalization.
Through time, the dynamics of values and institutions are such
that
values that were once institutionalized can nevertheless change,
forcing
a de- or re-institutionalizing process. For example, some
constellations
of values in the southwestern United States led to the creation
of pri-
vate property rights in water that facilitated market processes
(see Sa-
liba [1987] for an overview of marketing in that area). Some
led toward
natural resource institutions that simulate market-like
processes with
taxes and subsidies (a vast literature exists here, see Baumol
and Oates
[1975]). We now see how these institutions change as a result
of the
ongoing valuing and institutionalizing process, to reflect the
"cultural
context" [Albelda, Gunn, and Waller 1987, p. 11]. In some
cases, com-
modities have been taken out of the market to reflect changed
values
(for instance, pesticides like DDT); in other cases, commodities
have
been returned to the market (saccharin, for example). In both
kinds of
circumstances (and others), NI addresses precisely the
"institutionaliz-
ing" game going on behind the market [Dugger 1988, p. 984],
by looking
at both the deliberate self-interested "contracting" activity of
market
participants and the historical evolution of the beliefs and
values and
moral communities that subsequently shape the institutions. It
is to the
evolution of Florida's water institution that we now turn.
Florida's Evolution of the Rules of the Game
Florida's early history of generally uncontrolled growth and un-
guided natural resource use and development eventually led to
consid-
This content downloaded from 128.227.197.233 on Mon, 05
Nov 2018 16:00:57 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
1066 Gary D. Lynne and Jeffrey Burkhardt
erable environmental stress (for overviews, see Blake [1980,
esp. pp.
195-196] and Clark [1974, esp. pp. 43-46]). By 1970,
population was
doubling every twenty-five years statewide and doubling every
fourteen
years in seven south Florida counties [Blake 1980, p. 224].
Aquifers had
been damaged by salt water intrusion from overpumping in
coastal
areas, development had occurred in important aquifer recharge
areas,
and water quality had notably worsened. Unprecedented
droughts oc-
curred in 1961, 1962, 1967, and again in 1970-1971 [Blake
1980, p.
224]. The droughts increased many citizens' awareness of the
possibil-
ity of long-term water shortages and further reductions in water
quality,
given the anticipated continued influx of people into the state-
both
permanent residents and tourists. Many people were in the
process of
questioning the values and belief systems that had encouraged
rapid
development. Even development interests were concerned,
however,
that water scarcity might affect their ability to attract new
residents and
businesses to the state. Everyone seems to have begun to
question the
processes by which resources, especially water, were allocated.
By 1974,
the general attitude in Florida toward resource use had changed
[Blake
1980, p. 195]. Conservation and preservation became major
political
issues. By the mid- 1 970s the institutionalizing of a new set of
values
was well underway.
The severe South Florida drought of 1970-1971 precipitated a
series
of political efforts to address these concerns and apparent new
values
[Clark 1974, p. 125]. In 1971, a special conference was
organized by the
governor to bring together both professional and lay people
[Clark
1974, pp. 125-26] to address problems associated with
uncontrolled
growth and resource use. The conference served to highlight
the need
for reliable scientific and technical knowledge about the
problems, but
most importantly, it suggested that Floridans desired a long-
term po-
litical solution to those problems. The conference report laid
the
groundwork for dramatic institutional change. Subsequently, in
1972,
four major pieces of land and water legislation were enacted
[Clark
1974, pp. 126-36]. The law now more strictly regulated natural
re-
sources, provided for the purchase of environmentally sensitive
lands,
and mandated state-wide comprehensive planning. The Florida
Water
Resources Act ("the Act") focused on the regulation of well-
drilling,
surface water management, and consumptive use of water (see
Tilley,
Lynne, and Boggess [1985] for a discussion of the consumptive
use por-
tion].3 Commenting on this legislative activity the Governor
noted that
compared to other states Florida "would walk away with the
honors"
[Blake 1980, p. 223]. In fact, the legislation only started the
process of
This content downloaded from 128.227.197.233 on Mon, 05
Nov 2018 16:00:57 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
Evolution of Florida Water Institutions 1067
redirecting Florida's water institutions to reflect citizens'
broader envi-
ronmental concerns. The process has continued through
administrative
law in the water management districts put in place by the Act
as well
as in further growth management legislation during the 1 980s.
The Florida Water Resources Act drew heavily on the Maloney
Model Water Code [Maloney, Ausness, and Morris 1972]. The
Code,
intended for use in all of the eastern United States, has three
purposes:
to take into account the hydrologic interrelationship of all
types of water
resources in the state; to provide greater certainty than is
possible under
a court-administered reasonable use approach; yet to retain
sufficient flex-
ibility to make possible realistic long-range plans for the
conservation and
wise use of water resources and the elimination of waste
[Maloney, Aus-
ness, and Morris 1972, p. vii].
The Act incorporates all three purposes. A major assumption of
the Act
is that water administrative agencies need reliable knowledge
about hy-
drologic structures and patterns and other ecological
relationships. To
that end, professional staffs are charged with insuring that the
lat-
est information is used in advising the nine-member governing
board
in each district. The South Florida Water Management District,
for ex-
ample, employs more than 200 professionals (and over 1000
support
employees), many with advanced degrees in the revelant
academic dis-
ciplines. The five districts regularly fund academic research at
the
state's universities in addition to using consulting firms. Board
mem-
bers appointed by the governor are also to be "experts on
water" [Ma-
loney, Ausness, and Morris 1972, p. 79]. Although the
possibility of
electing the boards is now being considered, the original reason
for ap-
pointing the board members was to insure that such individuals
had
the necessary understanding of the hydrologic system.
The point of assembling all this expertise is planning, and
indeed,
planning represents a key feature of the Act. The State
Department of
Environmental Regulation has been charged with coordinating
plan-
ning in the five water districts that encompass the state.4
However, the
water districts themselves, not the state, do most of the
planning. This
structure is meant to insure that regional differences in both
hydrology
and values are adequately reflected in the process.
Once in place, the Act facilitated the evolution of a process for
deter-
mining both the value of water and its appropriate uses.
Notably, the
process facilitated by the Act fits John Commons's account of
evolving
reasonable value: Commons showed how value evolves through
politi-
cal negotiation in addition to market process [Gruchy 1972, p.
42]. As
This content downloaded from 128.227.197.233 on Mon, 05
Nov 2018 16:00:57 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
1068 Gary D. Lynne and Jeffrey Burkhardt
Commons noted, "Reasonable value changes with new
combinations
of circumstances and collective control, and is in process of
evolution
through changes in efficiency, scarcity, custom, politics, and
dominant
interests" [Commons 1934, p. 207]. In concordance with
Florida's Ad-
ministrative Procedure Act,5 the Act facilitates handling new
circum-
stances and changing values through negotiation and the use of
forms
of nonmarket interaction among those with varying interests,
such as
public meetings, hearings and workshops. Over and above the
question
of valuation, however, the Act also forces the districts to
decide what
the reasonable uses of water are for their areas. The districts
are not
without guidance on this question, however. Certain standards
of rea-
sonableness were incorporated into the institution reflecting a
range of
values associated with water. For example, individuals do not
need per-
mits to take water for domestic purposes [Maloney, Ausness,
and Mor-
ris 1972, p. 177], reflecting the primacy of individual rights to
this
needed resource.6 Private land may be condemned, however,
for con-
servation purposes [Maloney, Ausness, and Morris 1972, p.
148].
Moreover, transport across hydrologic boundaries (interdistrict
trans-
fer) is not permitted unless demonstrated to be in the public
interest.7
Users may not cause an "unmitigated adverse impact" on other
users,
defined in one district as a decrease of 10 percent or more in
the with-
drawal capability [South Florida Water Management District
1985, p.
B-6].
The standard of reasonableness was supplemented with the
concept
of beneficial use, reflecting the Maloney reasonable beneficial
use stan-
dard [Maloney, Capehart, and Hoofman 1979]. As defined by
Maloney
et al., the reasonable beneficial standard refers to: "The use of
water in
such quantity as is necessary for economic and efficient
utilization for
a purpose and in a manner which is both reasonable and
consistent
with the public interest."8 The beneficial use component refers
primar-
ily to the private interest (benefits and costs) in water,
reasonableness
involves the relationship of the private to the public interest.
The stan-
dard suggests economic efficiency can be pursued only in the
larger con-
text of also satisfying the public interest.
A main component of that public interest that underlies the
admin-
istrative structure is the value Floridians placed on what can be
referred
to as "the continuity of human life" [Tool, 1986, esp. p. 50, 57-
58]. The
Act expresses overriding concerns for wise use of water to
insure the
continuity of human life with the focus on public health,
safety, and
general welfare [Maloney, Ausness, and Morris 1972, p. 277,
279].9
Both the Code and the Act also emphasize the continuity of life
in fish,
This content downloaded from 128.227.197.233 on Mon, 05
Nov 2018 16:00:57 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
Evolution of Florida Water Institutions 1069
wildlife, and other natural systems [Maloney, Ausness, and
Morris
1972, p. 277].10 The long-term integrity of all water and
related resource
systems should be protected in all phases of the hydrologic
cycle [Ma-
loney, Ausness, and Morris 1972, p. 82]. Despite the
recognition of eco-
nomic efficiency in the goals of the Code and Act, the logical
inference
is that other values and perhaps even a "moral community"
with re-
spect to water operated to produce an institutional structure
that re-
flects those more fundamental values.
The important point is that Floridans established an
administrative,
rather than a market, structure for the determination of water
alloca-
tion and use. It is with respect to this outcome that NC theory
provides
little guidance. Indeed, NC theory may even hold that Floridans
were
(and continue to be) mistaken if not unreasonable in their
institution-
alizing process. NC theory maintains that whatever problems
exist in
allocation/use/valuation, laws should be enacted to remove
impedi-
ments to the natural evolution of water (and other
environmental re-
source) markets. Alternatively, taxes and subsidies should be
enacted
to emulate "natural" markets. Under these market or quasi-
market ar-
rangements the optimal long-run use would have been
achieved. Pop-
ulation growth, droughts, and the like would have only affected
the
relative prices of alternative uses.
For NI theory, to the contrary, the administrative structure put
in
place in Florida has an inherent reasonableness, given the
desires and
values of the population. Interestingly, many of the Rokeach
values can
be seen to have been specifically institutionalized in the Act
and in ad-
ministrative rules and regulations developed by each water
district
since 1972 [Rokeach 1973, p. 28]. Uncertainty has been
reduced (and
security enhanced): permits can be issued for up to twentyi
years and
the original permit holder will be given first consideration for
renewal. I '
Permit holders are expected to be obedient: water districts have
police
power to enforce rules.'2 Applicants should be honest: permits
can be
lost if false information has been used to get the permit.'3
Applicants
should be ambitious and hard working: permits can be lost for
nonuse
of water.14 Individual permit holders are encouraged to be
independent:
only minimal efforts are put into directing actual on-site water
using
practices.
More to the point is whether or not a moral community in the
sense
discussed above exists with respect to the allocation and use of
this re-
source. The idea of such a community of shared purposes is
arguably
apparent in the code that underlies the Act. The swiftness with
which
the state moved from initial identification of those problems to
an in-
This content downloaded from 128.227.197.233 on Mon, 05
Nov 2018 16:00:57 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
1070 Gary D. Lynne and Jeffrey Burkhardt
stitutional structure that addresses them suggests at least some
measure
of "shared purpose." The continuation of the mandate of the
Act in the
administrative activities of the water districts suggests some
degree of
continued commitment, as does the surprisingly small number
of legal
challenges to decisions of the water districts' boards. The
problem is
that even with this institutional structure in place and
continuing its
function, there remains conflict and competition over water in
Florida.
This may suggest that either (1) no moral community ever
existed, the
Act instead reflecting a somewhat accidental confluence of
self-
interested and environmental considerations; or (2) a
community did
exist, but no longer does: the institutional structure no longer
reflects
the values of Floridians with respect to water; or (3) the
community
still exists and the institutional structure continues to reflect it,
but that
fine tuning and "reinstitutionalizing" will be a continual
activity. We
favor the last explanation, but also realize further study of the
matter
is needed.
Floridians Have Yet to Address Competition
While the code and the Act give a workable framework within
which
to reduce conflict, problems remain. An especially difficult one
is re-
solving competition, especially during droughts.
Consumptive use permits currently specify an upper limit on
with-
drawals for some drought frequency, such as: "draw up to one
acre inch
per day on average given a rainfall year described by a 2-in- 10
drought
frequency."'5 As long as 2-in-O0, or wetter, rainfall years
occur, the user
can draw the one acre inch. If rainfall has been lower, however,
the
permit now only gives rights to participate in a process for
allocating
water (a competition) defined by provisions of a water shortage
plan
put in place by each water management district.'6
The "competition," however, has some very stringent and
limiting
rules, especially when compared to the rules underlying market
com-
petition. For example, after the South Florida Water
Management Dis-
trict declares a moderate, severe, extreme, or critical water
shortage,
suggesting the need for up to a 15, 30, 45, or 60 percent
reduction in
overall demand, a listing of priority areas and particular
allocations to
each class of user comes into force [South Florida Water
Management
District, 1982, p. 5 and Figure 21-1]. At the 45 percent level,
for exam-
ple, overhead agricultural sprinklers can only be operated from
7 p.m.
to 7 a.m., while low-volume agricultural irrigation systems can
be op-
erated without limit; domestic use is limited to 40 gallons per
person
This content downloaded from 128.227.197.233 on Mon, 05
Nov 2018 16:00:57 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
Evolution of Florida Water Institutions 1071
per day; and swimming pools in tourist hotels cannot be filled.
Alloca-
tion is by specific limits for each use in the district, with all
restrictions
centrally determined and made a part of the water shortage
rule.
The problem faced by water users in such a system can be
highlighted
with an excerpt from one such water shortage plan as
pertaining to ag-
riculture during a 45 percent shortfall: "The share of the total
agricul-
tural irrigation allocation available to each user will be based
on any
prioritization among crops the District establishes based on
economic
loss or equity considerations and the acreage and quantity of
withdraw-
als for which the user has been permitted" [South Florida Water
Man-
agement District 1982, p. 20]. Generally each class of water
user can
be subjected to a priortization and allocation process defined in
detail
by the district during each drought event. While such a process
must
comply with the Act (with the possibility of various kinds of
negoti-
ation and interaction, and in this sense, a process generating
reasonable
value as argued earlier in the case of evolving rules), we
question the
effectiveness of such a process for allocating water among
private sector
uses, both during droughts and over the long run.
The problem really is an information problem. Reliable
hydrologic
and value information about every gallon of water must be
available
to the forty-five people (five water districts, nine governing
board mem-
bers in each) charged with all the permit and water allocation
decisions
for the entire state. As noted, the boards do employ large, well-
trained
professional staffs to help the information problem. Much of
the $150
million spent each year for water management by the five
districts is
to generate information [Lynne 1988, p. 95]. Even so, it
appears impos-
sible for the boards and staffs to know how much water each
use should
have at all times [Lynne 1988, pp. 99-100]. Reliable knowledge
gener-
ated through research can provide a portion of the needed
information,
and public hearing processes can to some extent facilitate
determining
how much to allocate to each user. Practically speaking,
however, use-
ful information will always be in short supply if the only way
for indi-
viduals to interact is through the present political process.
Public
meetings and hearings, workshops, and other means of getting
informa-
tion to forty-five board members appear inadequate for their
task of
allocating billions of gallons of water to millions of users.
In the eyes of some observers, water or water rental markets
may
represent a better way for allocating this resource, especially
within
the private sector. As NC theory holds, individuals selling or
rent-
ing water would not do so unless a benefit was expected, and
the buy-
ers and renters would not want water unless a gain was
expected.
This content downloaded from 128.227.197.233 on Mon, 05
Nov 2018 16:00:57 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
1072 Gary D. Lynne and Jeffrey Burkhardt
Because both individuals gain, economic efficiency occurs.
Both the
competition-during-drought and information problems would be
obvi-
ated. During droughts, prices would simply rise: holders of
excess water
would eventually sell. No state- or district-wide information
about
value regarding private uses would be necessary, and
information
would be needed only about hydrology and the values
pertaining to the
public interest, both of which would still be the charge of the
districts.
As severe as these (and other) problems might be for the
administra-
tion of Florida's water policy, the fact is that Floridians would
probably
not tolerate a free market to resolve all the water allocation
decisions.
James Swaney [1988, p. 36] has noted the "shortsightedness" of
water
markets; markets may miss major value shifts, which seemingly
is a
major reason for the Act. The Florida community may favor
relatively
free water marketing or renting during short term droughts
(when val-
ues are stable) but only a very limited marketing for long-term
alloca-
tion, when values are shifting. Information about market prices
for
short-term water might prove especially helpful to the boards
during
droughts. Some limited marketing for long-term allocation may
also
provide insights into which uses might be encouraged and
which
should be discontinued, but only if major value changes can be
insti-
tutionalized in other processes.
Some marketing may also be a way to control those rent-
seekers who
remain. Individuals who would otherwise obtain resources by
putting
obstacles in the way of markets would now have to buy water
from
other people. The net result would be a sharing of the rent.
Basic admin-
istrative structures, however, would still be needed to insure
that other
values were considered: administrative and board review would
still
be needed to monitor transactions and to influence the direction
of wa-
ter markets. Indeed, not only is water "different" in the eyes of
Florid-
ians, it is too important to be left to the market. As Swaney has
noted,
society will not normally let such an important resource be
allocated
by the "Juggernaut market" [Swaney 1988, fn. 35, p. 43]. Yet,
"properly
administered water trading (could represent) an instrumental
institu-
tional adjustment" [Swaney 1988, p. 44]. The current
institutional
structure probably needs only some fine tuning, possibly
involving
some marketing, to further insure that it both reflects the
community's
(moral) evaluation and the desires for its economic and
efficient use.
The evolution of water markets in Florida would depend on a
num-
ber of considerations in addition to their information-
transmission or
efficiency-preserving functions: (1) Water markets will arise
only if the
other values Floridians hold (most importantly, the "continuity
of
This content downloaded from 128.227.197.233 on Mon, 05
Nov 2018 16:00:57 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
Evolution of Florida Water Institutions 1073
life") are secured. (2) Unconstrained "free" markets in the
sense of the
NC (seemingly immaculate) conception will arise only if
people gener-
ally believe either that there are no rent-seekers left in Florida
or that
the nature of the resource is such that rent-seeking is
minimized. How-
ever, (3) water markets may never evolve if the community's
values
associated with the water resource can be satisfied within some
form
of political/administrative process. The implication is that (4)
water
markets will arise, once the administrative structure has done
its job of
reinforcing in attitudes and behavior the idea that water
allocation and
use is a matter of community values. The question is whether
the insti-
tutional structure will reinforce that moral community, or fall
prey to
the "wealth maximization" model in its basic allocation
decisions.
Conclusions and Implications
Florida's water institutions originally evolved in a setting of
fear and
concern arising from water scarcity caused by rampant
economic devel-
opment. Fear and concern appears to have led to a coalescence
of atti-
tudes in the late 1960s among economic development interests
and
environmental preservation communities of the state, given the
general
support for a dramatically different water institution starting in
1972.
The 1972 Florida Water Resources Act (and the rules,
regulations, cus-
toms, and habits that have evolved since 1972) seemingly
reflect that
coalescence, which we have referred to as a moral community.
The Act
institutionalized the community's values and put in place a
process for
drawing out the practical implications of those values, as
reliable
knowledge about both the hydrologic system and the impacts of
growth, development, and conservation has become available.
The ad-
ministrative requirements imposed by the later institutions have
changed behavior, but those institutions already reflected a
changed at-
titude toward water resources. The institutions usually have
served to
reduce conflict. However, as conflict erupts again in the face of
institu-
tional rigidities (which may be a constant, under Veblen's
notion that
"whatever is, is wrong"), institutional adjustment will generally
be
needed. Both during and after adjustment, markets may serve a
useful
role, mainly because of the information transmission capability
of mar-
kets. As we suggested, however, the nature of those markets
may be
decidedly different from the market models proposed by
neoclassical
theory, dependent as they are on the existence of a moral
community.
Colorado, New Mexico, and other western U.S. water markets
appar-
ently function within the context of a moral community: in
nearly all
This content downloaded from 128.227.197.233 on Mon, 05
Nov 2018 16:00:57 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
1074 Gary D. Lynne and Jeffrey Burkhardt
cases, state and federal agencies administer both the market
and the
prices (see Saliba [1987]).
Markets may eventually emerge in Florida. Although the
Florida
Water Resources Act developed rules to reflect an
administrative re-
sponse to moral community, market-like institutions are not
necessar-
ily inconsistent with its intent. Frank J. Trelease has argued
that
If an easterner wants the best of water use laws, he could make
no better
start than first considering the provisions of the Model Code
for planning,
regulating and protecting water resources. But he should think
very hard
before he adopts the Code's system for distributing and
redistributing the
water allocated to the private sector [Trelease 1974, p. 213].
Trelease favors water rental markets, as well as sales of water
and sales
of water rights, for allocating water that has been set aside for
the pri-
vate sector [Trelease 1974, esp. pp. 222-223]. His point may
have some
validity: such administered markets may prove to be a good
way to
meet peoples' differing, secondary needs and values in the
private sec-
tor once basic "continuity of life" values are imbedded in the
institu-
tion reflecting the public interest.
Even so, some evidence exists for thinking that in many states,
including Florida, an extensive marketing structure will never
emerge.
Susan C. Nunn suggests that High Plains (particularly west
Texas)
farmers would not be favorably disposed toward water markets,
or any
other sort of institutional change that might affect distribution,
no mat-
ter how economically efficient [Nunn 1985, pp. 890-91]. As
noted ear-
lier, Shabman and Cox also seem to believe markets may not be
politically tractable in Virginia [Shabman and Cox 1986, p.
165].
One thing is clear: the evolution or lack of evolution of
markets (or
any other set of institutional arrangements) is better explained
through
NI analysis than through NC theory. This is particularly true
with re-
spect to water institutions. This is because NI theory provides a
more
empirical and realistic explanation of the emergence of
institutions on
the basis of individual and community values, and the
institutional
conditions under which people acquire, maintain, or change
their val-
ues and subsequent actions. In the case of Florida's water
institutions,
NI analysis provides the basis for an explanation of the
conditions un-
der which the non-market institutions evolved and will be
maintained,
insofar as they achieve values and objectives not easily reached
with
markets.
This content downloaded from 128.227.197.233 on Mon, 05
Nov 2018 16:00:57 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
Evolution of Florida Water Institutions 1075
Notes
1. Rokeach calls them instrumental values, but uses the
terminology some-
what differently than in NI theory. That is, Rokeach's use
suggests "func-
tion" or "means" or "mode of operation," such as "being
honest" or "being
capable" or "being intellectucal." While NI instrumental value
theory
might suggest that people pursue Rokeach instrumental values,
clearly NI
instrumental valuation has more referential content than simply
describing
a list of objectives.
2. This is not to suggest that Buchanan and other Public Choice
(PC) theorists
(such as Tullock) are neoclassical economists. As correctly
pointed out by
an anonymous referee, NC theorists "consider institutional
adjustment to
be outside the domain of economics. PC theorists investigate
choice of in-
stitutions using NC assumptions about maximizing
individuals." We do
believe, however, that differences often are blurred because of
the insis-
tence of the PC theorists on individuals only seeking self-
interest with little
regard for or influence from the community, as in the NC
theory.
3. Florida Statutes, Chapter 373.
4. Ibid., Chapter 373.036.
5. Ibid., Chapter 120.52.
6. Ibid., Chapter 373.219.
7. Ibid., Chapter 373.2295(10).
8. Ibid., Chapter 373.019(4).
9. Ibid., Chapter 373.016(h).
10. Ibid., Chapter 373.016(e).
11. Ibid., Chapters 373.236(1) and 373.233(2).
12. Ibid., Chapters 373,603.
13. Ibid., Chapter 373.243(1).
14. Ibid., Chapter 373.243(4).
15. A maximum day withdrawal is also generally specified, but
is not necessary
to the example being discussed.
16. Florida Administrative Code, Chap. 40.
References
Albelda, Randy, Christopher Gunn, and William Waller, ed.
1987. Alternatives
to Economic Orthodoxy. Armonk, N.Y.: M. E. Sharpe, Inc.
Anderson, Terry L. 1983. Ending the Policy Drought.
Baltimore: The Johns
Hopkins University Press.
Baumol, William J. and Wallace E. Oates. 1975. The Theory of
Environmental
Policy. Englewood Cliffs, N.J.: Prentice Hall, Inc.
Blake, Nelson M. 1980. Land into Water- Water into Land, A
History of Water
Management in Florida. Tallahassee,: University Presses of
Florida.
Brown, Lee, Brian McDonald, John Tysseling, and Charles
DuMars. 1982.
"Water Reallocation, Market Proficiency, and Conflicting
Social Values." In
This content downloaded from 128.227.197.233 on Mon, 05
Nov 2018 16:00:57 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
1076 Gary D. Lynne and Jeffrey Burkhardt
Water and Agriculture in the Western U.S.: Conservation,
Reallocation, and
Markets, ed. Gary D. Weatherford (Charles W. Howe, General
Editor), pp.
191-255. Boulder, Colo.: Studies in Water Policy and
Management, No. 2,
Westview Press, Inc.
Buchanan, James M. 1986. Liberty, Market, and State: Political
Economy in
the 1980's. London: Wheatsheaf Books LTD, Harvester Press
Publishing
Group.
. 1987. "The Constitution of Economic Policy." American
Economic
Review 77 (June): 243-50.
Buchanan, James M. and Gordon Tullock. 1967. The Calculus
of Consent. Ann
Arbor, Mich.: University of Michigan Press [1962].
Buchholz, Rogene. 1982. Business Environment and Public
Policy. Englewood
Cliffs, N.J.: Prentice-Hall.
Burkhardt, Jeffrey. 1988. "Crisis, Argument, and Agriculture."
Journal of Ag-
ricultural Ethics. 1 (Summer): 123-38.
Caldwell, Bruce. 1982. Beyond Positivism, Economic
Methodology in the Twen-
tieth Century. London: George Allen and Unwin.
Clark, Luther J. 1974. The Florida Experience, Land and Water
Policy in a
Growth State. Baltimore and London: Published for Resources
for the Fu-
ture, Inc. by Johns Hopkins University Press.
Commons, John R. 1934. Institutional Economics: Its Place in
Political Econ-
omy. Madison: University of Wisconsin Press.
Dallmayr, Fred, ed. 1978. From Contract to Community. New
York: Marcel
Dekker.
Downs, Anthony. 1957. An Economic Theory of Democracy.
New York: Har-
per and Brothers.
Dugger, William M. 1988. "A Research Agenda for
Institutional Economics."
Journal of Economic Issues 22 (December): 983-1002.
Gardner, B. Delworth. 1983. "Water Pricing and Rent Seeking
in California
Agriculture." In Water Rights, Scarce Resource Allocation,
Bureacracy, and
the Environment, ed. Terry L. Anderson, pp. 83-115. San
Francisco: Pacific
Institute for Public Policy Research.
Gordon, Wendell and John Adams. 1989. Economics as Social
Science. River-
dale, Md.: The Riverdale Company.
Gruchy, Allan G. 1972. Contemporary Economic Thought: The
Contribution
of Neo-Institutional Economics. Clifton, N.J.: Augustus M.
Kelley.
Hodgson, Geoffrey M. 1988. Economics and Institutions.
Philadelphia: Univer-
sity of Pennsylvania Press.
Howe, Charles W., Dennis R. Schurmeier, and W. Douglas
Shaw, Jr. 1986. "In-
novative Approaches to Water Allocation: The Potential for
Water Mar-
kets." Water Resources Research 22 (April): 439-45.
Lynne, Gary D. 1988. "Agricultural Water Modeling and
Economic Informa-
tion Needs Under the Model Water Code." Water Resources
Bulletin 24
(February): 95-101 .
McPherson, Michael S. 1984. "Limits on Self-Seeking, The
Role of Morality
in Economic Life." In Neoclassical Political Economy, The
Analysis of Rent-
Seeking and DUP Activities. ed. David C. Colander, pp. 71-85.
Cambridge,
Mass." Ballinger Publishing Company.
Maloney, Frank E., Richard C. Ausness, and J. Scott Morris.
1972. A Model
This content downloaded from 128.227.197.233 on Mon, 05
Nov 2018 16:00:57 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
Evolution of Florida Water Institutions 1077
Water Code With Commentary. Gainesville, Fla.: University of
Florida
Press.
Maloney, Frank E., Lynne C. Capehart, and Robert S.
Hoofman. 1979. "Flor-
ida's 'Reasonable Beneficial' Water Use Standard: Have East
and West
Met?" University of Florida Law Review 31 (Winter): 253-83.
Nunn, Susan C. 1985. "The Political Economy of Institutional
Change: A Dis-
tribution Criterion for Acceptance of Groundwater Rules."
Natural Re-
sources Journal 25 (October): 867-92.
Rokeach, Milton. 1973. The Nature of Human Values. New
York: The Free
Press.
. 1979. "From Individual to Institutional Values: With Special
Refer-
ence to the Values of Science." In Understanding Human
Values, Individual
and Societal. Ed. Milton Rokeach, pp. 47-70. New York: The
Free Press.
Sagoff, Mark. 1989. The Economy of the Earth. New York:
Cambridge Univer-
sity Press.
Saliba, Bonnie C. 1987. Water Markets in Theory and Practice.
Boulder and
London: Westview Press.
Schmid, A. Alan. 1987. Property, Power, and Public Choice:
An Inquiry into
Law and Economics. New York: Praeger Publishers (second
edition).
Shabman, Leonard and William E. Cox. 1986. "Costs of Water
Management
Institutions: The Case of Southeastern Virginia." In Scarce
Water and Insti-
tutional Change. Ed. Kenneth D. Frederick, pp. 134-70,
Washington, D.C.:
Resources for the Future.
South Florida Water Management District. 1985. "Basis of
Review for Water
Use Permit Applications Within the South Florida Water
Management Dis-
trict." West Palm Beach, Fla. Resource Control Department,
January.
South Florida Water Management District. 1982. "Water
Shortage Plan, Rules
of the South Florida Water Management District, Chapter 40E-
21." West
Palm Beach, Fla.; May 1982.
Swaney, James A. 1988. "Trading Water: Market Extension,
Social Improve-
ment, or What?" Journal of Economic Issues 22 (March): 33-
48.
Tilley, Marsha, Gary D. Lynne, and William G. Boggess. 1985.
Florida Water
Management District Rules and Regulations: Consumptive Use
Permits.
Florida Agricultural Experiment Station Circular S-317.
Gainesville, Fla.
University of Florida.
Tool, Marc R. 1986. Essays in Social Value Theory: A
Neoinstitutionalist Con-
tribution. Armonk, N.Y.: M. E. Sharpe, Inc.
Trelease, Frank J. 1974. "The Model Water Code, The Wise
Administrator and
the Goddam Bureaucrat." Natural Resources Journal 14 (April):
207-29.
Wandschneider, Philip R. 1986. "Neoclassical and
Institutionalist Explana-
tions of Changes in Northwest Water Institutions." Journal of
Economic Is-
sues 20 (March): 87-107.
This content downloaded from 128.227.197.233 on Mon, 05
Nov 2018 16:00:57 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
Contents105910601061106210631064106510661067106810691
0701071107210731074107510761077Issue Table of
ContentsJournal of Economic Issues, Vol. 24, No. 4 (Dec.,
1990), pp. 963-1241Front MatterNew Light on John Dewey,
Clarence Ayres, and the Development of Evolutionary
Economics [pp. 963-979]"New Thinking" in the Soviet
Economy: Lessons for Western Political Economists [pp. 981-
994]The Causes of Black Poverty: Evidence and Interpretation
[pp. 995-1016]The Rhetoric of Inquiry or the Sophistry of the
Status Quo? Exploring the Common Ground between Critical
Rhetoric and Institutional Economics [pp. 1017-1026]Why
Johnny (Ph.D., Economics) Can't Read: A Rhetorical Analysis
of Thorstein Veblen and a Response to Donald McCloskey's
"Rhetoric of Economics" [pp. 1027-1044]Retirement as an
Institution [pp. 1045-1057]The Evolution of Water Institutions
in Florida: A Neoinstitutionalist Perspective [pp. 1059-
1077]Client Consumption Patterns within an Income-Based
Energy Assistance Program [pp. 1079-1093]Institutional
Adjustment, Instrumental Efficiency, and Reasonable Value [pp.
1095-1107]Notes and CommunicationsInstrumental Value an
Eternal Verity? A Reply to Wendell Gordon [pp. 1109-
1122]Culture versus Social Value? A Response to Anne
Mayhew [pp. 1122-1133]Economic Reforms in Socialist
Economics: A Comment on Petr [pp. 1133-1137]Review:
Keynesianism, Monetarism, and the Crisis of the State: A
Review Article [pp. 1139-1146]Book ReviewsReview: Two
Reviews of William M. Dugger: "Corporate Hegemony" [pp.
1147-1155]Review: untitled [pp. 1157-1163]Review: untitled
[pp. 1163-1166]Review: untitled [pp. 1166-1168]Review:
untitled [pp. 1168-1172]Review: untitled [pp. 1172-
1175]Review: untitled [pp. 1175-1179]Review: untitled [pp.
1179-1181]Review: untitled [pp. 1181-1186]Review: untitled
[pp. 1186-1189]Review: untitled [pp. 1190-1193]Review:
untitled [pp. 1193-1196]Review: untitled [pp. 1196-
1197]Review: untitled [pp. 1198-1199]Author Index: Volumes I
- XXIV (1967-1990) [pp. 1201-1241]Back Matter

More Related Content

Similar to AEB 2451 Economics of Resource Use Lecturer Misti Sharp .docx

Gay Marriages Essay
Gay Marriages EssayGay Marriages Essay
Gay Marriages Essay
Sheila Espinoza
 
Global Warming Argument Essay
Global Warming Argument EssayGlobal Warming Argument Essay
Global Warming Argument Essay
Brenda Thomas
 
Save Water Save Earth Essay. 10 Lines on Save Water in English for Kids - You...
Save Water Save Earth Essay. 10 Lines on Save Water in English for Kids - You...Save Water Save Earth Essay. 10 Lines on Save Water in English for Kids - You...
Save Water Save Earth Essay. 10 Lines on Save Water in English for Kids - You...
Shannon Edwards
 
School Experience Essay. How to write a learning experience essay - copywrite...
School Experience Essay. How to write a learning experience essay - copywrite...School Experience Essay. How to write a learning experience essay - copywrite...
School Experience Essay. How to write a learning experience essay - copywrite...
Ashley Mason
 
Lady Macbeth Essay.pdf
Lady Macbeth Essay.pdfLady Macbeth Essay.pdf
Lady Macbeth Essay.pdf
Renee Spahn
 
Article· Kokmen, L. (2008, March-April). Environmental justice f.docx
Article· Kokmen, L. (2008, March-April). Environmental justice f.docxArticle· Kokmen, L. (2008, March-April). Environmental justice f.docx
Article· Kokmen, L. (2008, March-April). Environmental justice f.docx
davezstarr61655
 

Similar to AEB 2451 Economics of Resource Use Lecturer Misti Sharp .docx (20)

Market Failure Essay
Market Failure EssayMarket Failure Essay
Market Failure Essay
 
Gay Marriages Essay
Gay Marriages EssayGay Marriages Essay
Gay Marriages Essay
 
Essays On Drinking And Driving
Essays On Drinking And DrivingEssays On Drinking And Driving
Essays On Drinking And Driving
 
Global Warming Argument Essay
Global Warming Argument EssayGlobal Warming Argument Essay
Global Warming Argument Essay
 
Global Warming Argument Essay.pdf
Global Warming Argument Essay.pdfGlobal Warming Argument Essay.pdf
Global Warming Argument Essay.pdf
 
Save Water Save Earth Essay. 10 Lines on Save Water in English for Kids - You...
Save Water Save Earth Essay. 10 Lines on Save Water in English for Kids - You...Save Water Save Earth Essay. 10 Lines on Save Water in English for Kids - You...
Save Water Save Earth Essay. 10 Lines on Save Water in English for Kids - You...
 
School Experience Essay. How to write a learning experience essay - copywrite...
School Experience Essay. How to write a learning experience essay - copywrite...School Experience Essay. How to write a learning experience essay - copywrite...
School Experience Essay. How to write a learning experience essay - copywrite...
 
Samples Of Dissertation Proposals. Writing A Disser
Samples Of Dissertation Proposals. Writing A DisserSamples Of Dissertation Proposals. Writing A Disser
Samples Of Dissertation Proposals. Writing A Disser
 
Time Management Tips Essay
Time Management Tips EssayTime Management Tips Essay
Time Management Tips Essay
 
Social Environment Accounting
Social Environment AccountingSocial Environment Accounting
Social Environment Accounting
 
This Birthday Writing Paper Comes With 2 Different Desi
This Birthday Writing Paper Comes With 2 Different DesiThis Birthday Writing Paper Comes With 2 Different Desi
This Birthday Writing Paper Comes With 2 Different Desi
 
Problems with QE aka Printing Money - sanders richard - csiro paper - nub of ...
Problems with QE aka Printing Money - sanders richard - csiro paper - nub of ...Problems with QE aka Printing Money - sanders richard - csiro paper - nub of ...
Problems with QE aka Printing Money - sanders richard - csiro paper - nub of ...
 
Good Words For A Definition Essay.pdfGood Words For A Definition Essay
Good Words For A Definition Essay.pdfGood Words For A Definition EssayGood Words For A Definition Essay.pdfGood Words For A Definition Essay
Good Words For A Definition Essay.pdfGood Words For A Definition Essay
 
Essay About Environment. Helping the environment essay
Essay About Environment. Helping the environment essayEssay About Environment. Helping the environment essay
Essay About Environment. Helping the environment essay
 
Lady Macbeth Essay.pdf
Lady Macbeth Essay.pdfLady Macbeth Essay.pdf
Lady Macbeth Essay.pdf
 
Imperialism Dbq Essay
Imperialism Dbq EssayImperialism Dbq Essay
Imperialism Dbq Essay
 
Revisiting the commons local lessons global challenges
Revisiting the commons local lessons global challengesRevisiting the commons local lessons global challenges
Revisiting the commons local lessons global challenges
 
Ap English Argument Essay Introduction. Online assignment writing service.
Ap English Argument Essay Introduction. Online assignment writing service.Ap English Argument Essay Introduction. Online assignment writing service.
Ap English Argument Essay Introduction. Online assignment writing service.
 
Write A Short Essay On Healthy Food Essay Writing English - YouTube
Write A Short Essay On Healthy Food  Essay Writing  English - YouTubeWrite A Short Essay On Healthy Food  Essay Writing  English - YouTube
Write A Short Essay On Healthy Food Essay Writing English - YouTube
 
Article· Kokmen, L. (2008, March-April). Environmental justice f.docx
Article· Kokmen, L. (2008, March-April). Environmental justice f.docxArticle· Kokmen, L. (2008, March-April). Environmental justice f.docx
Article· Kokmen, L. (2008, March-April). Environmental justice f.docx
 

More from coubroughcosta

After reading The Cultural Meaning of Suicide What Does That Mean.docx
After reading The Cultural Meaning of Suicide What Does That Mean.docxAfter reading The Cultural Meaning of Suicide What Does That Mean.docx
After reading The Cultural Meaning of Suicide What Does That Mean.docx
coubroughcosta
 
AFTER READING THE BECOMING MODERN ESSAY, ANSWER THE FOLLOWING.docx
AFTER READING THE BECOMING MODERN ESSAY, ANSWER THE FOLLOWING.docxAFTER READING THE BECOMING MODERN ESSAY, ANSWER THE FOLLOWING.docx
AFTER READING THE BECOMING MODERN ESSAY, ANSWER THE FOLLOWING.docx
coubroughcosta
 
After reading the case study prepare Assignment One - Collecting I.docx
After reading the case study prepare Assignment One - Collecting I.docxAfter reading the case study prepare Assignment One - Collecting I.docx
After reading the case study prepare Assignment One - Collecting I.docx
coubroughcosta
 
After reading the assigned resources about leadership types and .docx
After reading the assigned resources about leadership types and .docxAfter reading the assigned resources about leadership types and .docx
After reading the assigned resources about leadership types and .docx
coubroughcosta
 

More from coubroughcosta (20)

After reviewing the policy brief by the Urban Institute on the pros .docx
After reviewing the policy brief by the Urban Institute on the pros .docxAfter reviewing the policy brief by the Urban Institute on the pros .docx
After reviewing the policy brief by the Urban Institute on the pros .docx
 
After reviewing the Psychosocial Care of the Elderly source found in.docx
After reviewing the Psychosocial Care of the Elderly source found in.docxAfter reviewing the Psychosocial Care of the Elderly source found in.docx
After reviewing the Psychosocial Care of the Elderly source found in.docx
 
After reviewing the Getta Byte Transcript (attached word document), .docx
After reviewing the Getta Byte Transcript (attached word document), .docxAfter reviewing the Getta Byte Transcript (attached word document), .docx
After reviewing the Getta Byte Transcript (attached word document), .docx
 
After reviewing chapter11( Facilitating Marketing Behaviors), chapte.docx
After reviewing chapter11( Facilitating Marketing Behaviors), chapte.docxAfter reviewing chapter11( Facilitating Marketing Behaviors), chapte.docx
After reviewing chapter11( Facilitating Marketing Behaviors), chapte.docx
 
After reading The Cultural Meaning of Suicide What Does That Mean.docx
After reading The Cultural Meaning of Suicide What Does That Mean.docxAfter reading The Cultural Meaning of Suicide What Does That Mean.docx
After reading The Cultural Meaning of Suicide What Does That Mean.docx
 
After reading through the Chapter1 to Chapter3, its reasonable to st.docx
After reading through the Chapter1 to Chapter3, its reasonable to st.docxAfter reading through the Chapter1 to Chapter3, its reasonable to st.docx
After reading through the Chapter1 to Chapter3, its reasonable to st.docx
 
After reading the SENSE4US document provided, what are your thou.docx
After reading the SENSE4US document provided, what are your thou.docxAfter reading the SENSE4US document provided, what are your thou.docx
After reading the SENSE4US document provided, what are your thou.docx
 
After reading the section titled Dominant Microprocessor Company In.docx
After reading the section titled Dominant Microprocessor Company In.docxAfter reading the section titled Dominant Microprocessor Company In.docx
After reading the section titled Dominant Microprocessor Company In.docx
 
After reading the SENSE4US document provided, what are your thoughts.docx
After reading the SENSE4US document provided, what are your thoughts.docxAfter reading the SENSE4US document provided, what are your thoughts.docx
After reading the SENSE4US document provided, what are your thoughts.docx
 
After reading the RN Safe Staffing Act and the role of the ANA.docx
After reading the RN Safe Staffing Act and the role of the ANA.docxAfter reading the RN Safe Staffing Act and the role of the ANA.docx
After reading the RN Safe Staffing Act and the role of the ANA.docx
 
After reading the reference documents attached, Discuss what p.docx
After reading the reference documents attached, Discuss what p.docxAfter reading the reference documents attached, Discuss what p.docx
After reading the reference documents attached, Discuss what p.docx
 
After reading the required articles this week .please write a resear.docx
After reading the required articles this week .please write a resear.docxAfter reading the required articles this week .please write a resear.docx
After reading the required articles this week .please write a resear.docx
 
After reading the information about James Bain and Craig Richard Col.docx
After reading the information about James Bain and Craig Richard Col.docxAfter reading the information about James Bain and Craig Richard Col.docx
After reading the information about James Bain and Craig Richard Col.docx
 
AFTER READING THE BECOMING MODERN ESSAY, ANSWER THE FOLLOWING.docx
AFTER READING THE BECOMING MODERN ESSAY, ANSWER THE FOLLOWING.docxAFTER READING THE BECOMING MODERN ESSAY, ANSWER THE FOLLOWING.docx
AFTER READING THE BECOMING MODERN ESSAY, ANSWER THE FOLLOWING.docx
 
After reading the case study prepare Assignment One - Collecting I.docx
After reading the case study prepare Assignment One - Collecting I.docxAfter reading the case study prepare Assignment One - Collecting I.docx
After reading the case study prepare Assignment One - Collecting I.docx
 
After reading the assigned resources about leadership types and .docx
After reading the assigned resources about leadership types and .docxAfter reading the assigned resources about leadership types and .docx
After reading the assigned resources about leadership types and .docx
 
After reading the assigned readings and The Loving Family Case .docx
After reading the assigned readings and The Loving Family Case .docxAfter reading the assigned readings and The Loving Family Case .docx
After reading the assigned readings and The Loving Family Case .docx
 
After reading the article by Leo, describe the difference between th.docx
After reading the article by Leo, describe the difference between th.docxAfter reading the article by Leo, describe the difference between th.docx
After reading the article by Leo, describe the difference between th.docx
 
After reading Rebore (2015), Chapter 9, discuss collective bargainin.docx
After reading Rebore (2015), Chapter 9, discuss collective bargainin.docxAfter reading Rebore (2015), Chapter 9, discuss collective bargainin.docx
After reading Rebore (2015), Chapter 9, discuss collective bargainin.docx
 
After reading Horace Miner’s Body Ritual Among the Nacirema,” r.docx
After reading Horace Miner’s Body Ritual Among the Nacirema,” r.docxAfter reading Horace Miner’s Body Ritual Among the Nacirema,” r.docx
After reading Horace Miner’s Body Ritual Among the Nacirema,” r.docx
 

Recently uploaded

The basics of sentences session 3pptx.pptx
The basics of sentences session 3pptx.pptxThe basics of sentences session 3pptx.pptx
The basics of sentences session 3pptx.pptx
heathfieldcps1
 

Recently uploaded (20)

How to setup Pycharm environment for Odoo 17.pptx
How to setup Pycharm environment for Odoo 17.pptxHow to setup Pycharm environment for Odoo 17.pptx
How to setup Pycharm environment for Odoo 17.pptx
 
How to Manage Global Discount in Odoo 17 POS
How to Manage Global Discount in Odoo 17 POSHow to Manage Global Discount in Odoo 17 POS
How to Manage Global Discount in Odoo 17 POS
 
COMMUNICATING NEGATIVE NEWS - APPROACHES .pptx
COMMUNICATING NEGATIVE NEWS - APPROACHES .pptxCOMMUNICATING NEGATIVE NEWS - APPROACHES .pptx
COMMUNICATING NEGATIVE NEWS - APPROACHES .pptx
 
HMCS Max Bernays Pre-Deployment Brief (May 2024).pptx
HMCS Max Bernays Pre-Deployment Brief (May 2024).pptxHMCS Max Bernays Pre-Deployment Brief (May 2024).pptx
HMCS Max Bernays Pre-Deployment Brief (May 2024).pptx
 
Food safety_Challenges food safety laboratories_.pdf
Food safety_Challenges food safety laboratories_.pdfFood safety_Challenges food safety laboratories_.pdf
Food safety_Challenges food safety laboratories_.pdf
 
Tatlong Kwento ni Lola basyang-1.pdf arts
Tatlong Kwento ni Lola basyang-1.pdf artsTatlong Kwento ni Lola basyang-1.pdf arts
Tatlong Kwento ni Lola basyang-1.pdf arts
 
21st_Century_Skills_Framework_Final_Presentation_2.pptx
21st_Century_Skills_Framework_Final_Presentation_2.pptx21st_Century_Skills_Framework_Final_Presentation_2.pptx
21st_Century_Skills_Framework_Final_Presentation_2.pptx
 
The basics of sentences session 3pptx.pptx
The basics of sentences session 3pptx.pptxThe basics of sentences session 3pptx.pptx
The basics of sentences session 3pptx.pptx
 
OSCM Unit 2_Operations Processes & Systems
OSCM Unit 2_Operations Processes & SystemsOSCM Unit 2_Operations Processes & Systems
OSCM Unit 2_Operations Processes & Systems
 
Basic Civil Engineering first year Notes- Chapter 4 Building.pptx
Basic Civil Engineering first year Notes- Chapter 4 Building.pptxBasic Civil Engineering first year Notes- Chapter 4 Building.pptx
Basic Civil Engineering first year Notes- Chapter 4 Building.pptx
 
Accessible Digital Futures project (20/03/2024)
Accessible Digital Futures project (20/03/2024)Accessible Digital Futures project (20/03/2024)
Accessible Digital Futures project (20/03/2024)
 
Basic Intentional Injuries Health Education
Basic Intentional Injuries Health EducationBasic Intentional Injuries Health Education
Basic Intentional Injuries Health Education
 
Graduate Outcomes Presentation Slides - English
Graduate Outcomes Presentation Slides - EnglishGraduate Outcomes Presentation Slides - English
Graduate Outcomes Presentation Slides - English
 
How to Add a Tool Tip to a Field in Odoo 17
How to Add a Tool Tip to a Field in Odoo 17How to Add a Tool Tip to a Field in Odoo 17
How to Add a Tool Tip to a Field in Odoo 17
 
TỔNG ÔN TẬP THI VÀO LỚP 10 MÔN TIẾNG ANH NĂM HỌC 2023 - 2024 CÓ ĐÁP ÁN (NGỮ Â...
TỔNG ÔN TẬP THI VÀO LỚP 10 MÔN TIẾNG ANH NĂM HỌC 2023 - 2024 CÓ ĐÁP ÁN (NGỮ Â...TỔNG ÔN TẬP THI VÀO LỚP 10 MÔN TIẾNG ANH NĂM HỌC 2023 - 2024 CÓ ĐÁP ÁN (NGỮ Â...
TỔNG ÔN TẬP THI VÀO LỚP 10 MÔN TIẾNG ANH NĂM HỌC 2023 - 2024 CÓ ĐÁP ÁN (NGỮ Â...
 
80 ĐỀ THI THỬ TUYỂN SINH TIẾNG ANH VÀO 10 SỞ GD – ĐT THÀNH PHỐ HỒ CHÍ MINH NĂ...
80 ĐỀ THI THỬ TUYỂN SINH TIẾNG ANH VÀO 10 SỞ GD – ĐT THÀNH PHỐ HỒ CHÍ MINH NĂ...80 ĐỀ THI THỬ TUYỂN SINH TIẾNG ANH VÀO 10 SỞ GD – ĐT THÀNH PHỐ HỒ CHÍ MINH NĂ...
80 ĐỀ THI THỬ TUYỂN SINH TIẾNG ANH VÀO 10 SỞ GD – ĐT THÀNH PHỐ HỒ CHÍ MINH NĂ...
 
This PowerPoint helps students to consider the concept of infinity.
This PowerPoint helps students to consider the concept of infinity.This PowerPoint helps students to consider the concept of infinity.
This PowerPoint helps students to consider the concept of infinity.
 
Google Gemini An AI Revolution in Education.pptx
Google Gemini An AI Revolution in Education.pptxGoogle Gemini An AI Revolution in Education.pptx
Google Gemini An AI Revolution in Education.pptx
 
FICTIONAL SALESMAN/SALESMAN SNSW 2024.pdf
FICTIONAL SALESMAN/SALESMAN SNSW 2024.pdfFICTIONAL SALESMAN/SALESMAN SNSW 2024.pdf
FICTIONAL SALESMAN/SALESMAN SNSW 2024.pdf
 
Interdisciplinary_Insights_Data_Collection_Methods.pptx
Interdisciplinary_Insights_Data_Collection_Methods.pptxInterdisciplinary_Insights_Data_Collection_Methods.pptx
Interdisciplinary_Insights_Data_Collection_Methods.pptx
 

AEB 2451 Economics of Resource Use Lecturer Misti Sharp .docx

  • 1. AEB 2451: Economics of Resource Use Lecturer: Misti Sharp 1 Assignment 10: Common Pool Resources Instructions: You may work in groups but you must turn in your own work! Indicate on the front page who you worked with (max 3 people). An electronic copy must be submitted online before midnight on Friday. Show all work so that partial credit may be given. This homework is worth 15 points total. 1) Read about the Atlantic Cod and the human “Tragedy of the Commons” article: http://www.wbur.org/cognoscenti/2014/12/03/overfishing- georges-bank-david-ropeik and reflect on why, economically, a fisherman like Tony could earn so much money without a degree “back in the day.” Were the Cod fishermen of years passed truly taking into account the full opportunity cost when they were behaving as they were? (3 points) 2) Suppose that the total benefit and total cost for a cod fisherman in the 1970s was as given in the table below where one boat could garner $9,000 in total fish revenue and $5,000 in total costs. Use this information to answer the next 3 questions. a. Complete the following table rounding to 1 decimal if necessary (3 points):
  • 2. # of Boats Total Benefit (000s) Total Costs (000s) Average Benefit Marginal Benefit Marginal cost 1 9 5 2 17 10 3 24 15 4 30 20 5 35 25 6 39 30 7 41 35 8 43 40 9 44 45 10 44 50 b. If the fisher were to have accepted the scientific evidence instead of fighting it and stopped fishing at the economically efficient level, how many boats
  • 3. would have been released into the Gulf of Maine? (3 points) c. Given that the cod fishery was subject to tragedy, how many boats were likely released into the Gulf of Maine? (3 points) 3) Read the following article and discuss how we are responding to the lack of Cod in the US: https://www.usnews.com/news/best-states/maine/articles/2017- 03-24/maines-cod-fishermen-have- worst-year-in-history In the “Global Scarcity” part of the course, we talked about becoming self- sufficient in food production. Would those tactics work for this fishery resource? Why or why not? (3 points) AEB 2451: Economics of Resource Use Lecturer: Misti Sharp 2 4) Read the attached article by Lynne and Burkhart (1990) about Florida Water Institutions. Discuss how water is managed in Florida. From a neoclassical theory perspective, does it appear as if it is possible to allocate water efficiently in Florida? What is required for efficient allocation using a neoinstitutional approach? Based on the discussion provided by the article, are you surprised that there have been “water
  • 4. wars” in Florida in recent years? Answer all questions fully for full credit. (3 points) The Evolution of Water Institutions in Florida: A Neoinstitutionalist Perspective Author(s): Gary D. Lynne and Jeffrey Burkhardt Source: Journal of Economic Issues, Vol. 24, No. 4 (Dec., 1990), pp. 1059-1077 Published by: Taylor & Francis, Ltd. Stable URL: https://www.jstor.org/stable/4226346 Accessed: 05-11-2018 16:00 UTC JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide range of content in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and facilitate new forms of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact [email protected] Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available at https://about.jstor.org/terms Taylor & Francis, Ltd. is collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend access to Journal of Economic Issues
  • 5. This content downloaded from 128.227.197.233 on Mon, 05 Nov 2018 16:00:57 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms JeI JOURNAL OF ECONOMIC ISSUES Vol. XXIV No. 4 December 1990 The Evolution of Water Institutions in Florida: A Neoinstitutionalist Perspective Gary D. Lynne and Jeffrey Burkhardt In most areas of the United States, water has not been considered tradeable in markets like other basic commodities (food, clothing, and shelter). Neoclassical (NC) theorists frequently refer somewhat dispar- agingly to this phenomenon as the "water is different syndrome," and go on to suggest that the results of the non-market allocation of water are less than optimal [see Gardner 1983, p. 85]. Since people involved in water institutions are "rent-seekers" [see Gardner 1983, p. 104-5, 1 13; Anderson 1983, Chap. 4]-a description that tends to give visions of evil wealth stealers busily creating ways to take or to keep
  • 6. wealth from others-society, as a result, has to play a "negative sum game" [Anderson 1983, p. 19]. This detracts from the ability of good wealth creators to maximize wealth. The NC solution to this problem, there- fore, nearly always involves proposing a system of tradeable water rights and a market process to replace the administrative structure that has evolved in some states. This is the only hope for alleviating the "policy drought" [Anderson 1983]. The NC presumption seems to be that all conflict arising from scarcity (and from differing values, beliefs, The authors are, respectively, Professor ofAgricultural Economics andAssociate Profes- sor of Ethics and Public Policy in the Food and Resource Economics Department at the University of Florida, Gainesville. They are grateful to Roy R. Carriker and to anonymous JEI reviewers for helpful comments. This is Florida Agricultural Experiment Station Jour- nal Series No. R-00522. 1059 This content downloaded from 128.227.197.233 on Mon, 05 Nov 2018 16:00:57 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
  • 7. 1060 Gary D. Lynne and Jeffrey Burkhardt attitudes and behavior) is reduced substantially and sufficiently when policy facilitates the efficiency dynamics of markets. Analysts in the neoinstitutional (NI) tradition do not appear to find the political and social reality surrounding water either surprising or problematical. For example, Lee Brown et al. [1982, p. 194] have noted how finding appropriate western U.S. water institutions has always in- volved solving a problem in political economy and not just finding an institution that will efficiently generate wealth. Leonard Shabman and William E. Cox [1986, p. 134] have argued that economic efficiency may not be the main concern or desired goal of Virginia water institu- tions. Even if economic efficiency motivated institutional change, any move to marketing "should be subjected to a benefit-cost comparison" with other processes [Shabman and Cox 1986, p. 165]. Water markets would likely be possible only after "protracted political debate" if ever. Shabman and Cox note how the Virginia legislature has consistently rejected moves toward water marketing [Shabman and Cox, 1986, p. 165]. Regarding rent-seeking, Michael S. McPherson has argued that
  • 8. self seeking with respect to resources has cultural and moral limits, so that the view that non-market water institutions always reflect and serve the interests of wealth stealers may not be defensible [McPherson 1984, p. 71]. Indeed, water institutions may instead reflect more fun- damental social values that may serve to influence and constrain the behavior of potential rent-seekers. This article explores the appropriateness of NI theory for explaining the character and evolution of water institutions. The focus of this anal- ysis is Florida's efforts over the past two decades to deal with "the water problem." Others have used NI theory to analyze water institutions. Philip R. Wandschneider found NI theory suitable for explaining re- cent institutional water change in the Pacific Northwest: efficiency gains were not even the issue; the issue was conflict and who was to have access to and control over water [Wandschneider 1986, esp. p. 97]. James A. Swaney used NI theory to improve our understanding of why water markets are not found extensively in the arid western United States, although he suggests that instituting water markets could prove to be a positive change [Swaney 1988]. Swaney suggests, however, ad-
  • 9. ministered markets as opposed to the "market system" suggested in NC theory [Swaney 1988, pp. 43, 44]. Charles Howe, et al. advocate the market system, but they also recognize potential market shortcomings [Howe, Schurmeier, and Shaw 1986, p. 440]. An inference could be drawn from their analysis that other possible goals for water policy, such as equity, fairness, and "socially responsible water allocation," This content downloaded from 128.227.197.233 on Mon, 05 Nov 2018 16:00:57 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms Evolution of Florida Water Institutions 1061 may be better accounted for in NI theory. We hypothesize that insofar as NI theory explains the existence and evolution of water institutions in Florida, it may also provide some clues as to the likely future course of Florida water institutions, in particular, the possible evolution of wa- ter markets. Contrasting Theories of Humans and Society One of the reasons NI theory better explains the system of water-
  • 10. resource allocation in Florida is that NI theory explicitly addresses the variety of motives and values that underlies individual and collective actions (see Hodgson [1988, p. xvi, 13, 16]). This is in contrast to NC theory, which assumes that the main, if not exclusive, determinant of individual and collective behavior is utility-maximization. For indi- viduals, utility maximizing consists of (1) determining how much time and effort will be devoted to obtaining more income, conceived as the leisure/work tradeoff [all objectives (values) other than the ones satis- fied with money goods are subsumed under "leisure"]; and (2) purchas- ing as many market goods as possible with the income (profit, wealth) available. As each individual maximizes utility within the constraints of her or his own "leisure" (other objectives) choice, resource con- straints, and the utility-maximizing behavior of others, a "social opti- mum" is assumed to result. We will return to this below. NI theory assumes that individual (and collective) behavior results from a considerably more complex set of factors: an individual's be- havior reflects priorities and trade-offs among a large number of values and objectives (Wendell Gordon and John Adams [1989, pp.
  • 11. 101-114] summarize several different views on this matter, pp. 101-114). Inter- action occurs within the context of others' similar (or different) kinds of trade-priorities and trade-offs. Given this assumption, NI analysts attempt to identify the range of underlying values, beliefs, and attitudes (and to determine the origin of each) that influence behavior and do not subsume all such values and beliefs under the "leisure" concept. It might be found, for example, that some individuals predominately act to acquire profits (having traded off leisure for money), while others do not exhibit profit-maximizing behavior at all [Tool 1986, p. 184]. In NI theory, however, the latter have traded off "other values" against profit, not simply leisure. For NI theory, since all actions reflect both the values of the individual and her or his cultural context (that is, oth- ers' values), explaining behavior is an empirical matter: what values, beliefs, and attitudes, are motivating people? In NC theory, to the con- This content downloaded from 128.227.197.233 on Mon, 05 Nov 2018 16:00:57 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
  • 12. 1062 Gary D. Lynne and Jeffrey Burkhardt trary, the maximization view is an untested assumption, or a method- ological convenience [Caldwell 1982]. Operationally, NI theory is in this respect consistent with and in some respects dependent upon the work of social psychologists such as Milton Rokeach [1973] (see also [Hodgson 1988, chaps. 3-6], in deter- mining what values people actually hold. Contrary to the NC maximi- zation model, Rokeach suggests that there is a multiplicity of values that people pursue or use as standards for determining the means and ends for behavior [Rokeach 1973, p. 13]; compare Tool [1986, p. 8]. Rokeach distinguishes between end-state or terminal values, and func- tional' values pursued to help in achieving end-state values. Based upon extensive empirical work, Rokeach has identified the following prevalent end-state or terminal values: a comfortable life, an exciting life, a sense of accomplishment, a world of peace, equality, family secu- rity, freedom, happiness, inner harmony, mature love, national secu- rity, pleasure, salvation, self-respect, social recognition, true friendship, and wisdom [Rokeach 1973, p. 28]. Functional values include:
  • 13. ambi- tion, broadmindedness, capability, cheerfulness, cleanliness, courage, helpfulness, honesty, imaginativeness, independence, as well as being intellectual, logical, loving, obedient, polite, responsible, and self- controlled. Note that most values cannot generally be purchased with more money. Given different accounts of individual psychology, the sociology of NC and NI theory also appears quite different. For NC theory, the as- sumption that individuals always maximize income (subject to internal and external constraints) leads directly to the position that all "normal" interactions among people are market interactions. In theory, this in- cludes political interactions [Downs 1957; Buchanan and Tullock 1967]. Although NC theorists tend to ignore basic institutions- in- cluding the market as institution (see Hodgson [1988, Chap. 8])-there is probably at least implicit agreement among them with Buchanan's account2 of how neoclassical assumptions also explain the origin and subsequent working of basic institutions in a society. James M. Buchanan and Gordon Tullock argue that institutions arise
  • 14. because of (a) the need for public safety and security, including enforce- able contracts; and (b) information and other transaction costs [Bu- chanan and Turlock 1967, pp. 47-62; Buchanan 1986, p. 11 1]. Without a suitable institution (a legal or moral device serving to stabilize mar- keting and other human interaction), no productive human interaction would occur. Markets, for example, would not function if either there are no enforceable contracts or if the participants are not (at least mini- This content downloaded from 128.227.197.233 on Mon, 05 Nov 2018 16:00:57 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms Evolution of Florida Water Institutions 1063 mally) capable of obtaining the requisite information to participate freely in the market. According to Buchanan, institutions are therefore to be understood as having been the result of an agreement that indi- viduals entered into at some point (or hypothetically) that established the fundamental "constitutional" principles on which subsequent inter- actions are to be based. With a "just" background institution in place,
  • 15. individuals can simply pursue their self-interest. So long as the rules operate, we can ignore the reasons and values that went into the intitial agreement. What Buchanan sees as motivating people to "join" the contract, then, is maximization of self-interest [Buchanan 1987, p. 245; also see Buchanan and Tullock 1967, pp. 11-15]. The resultant "constitution" -although this equally applies to any institution-reflects the wealth maximizing goal, although the institutionalizing process establishes formal rules for guaranteeing that transactions will be optimal in this regard. Whatever other values people have besides maximization of in- come-if they have other values-will either be reflected in market ac- tivities (that is, prices), or will be taken care of by various nonmarket activities (including institutions). Generally, however, nonmarket ac- tivities and institutions are inefficient, and hence will not be "con- tracted into." In contrast, NI theory attempts to explain both market and nonmar- ket institutions without the a priori assumption that the reason people enter into society (or participate in any set of institutions) is to maximize self-interest. Moreover, NI theory does not assume
  • 16. that non- market institutions are generally non-optimal and that markets are gen- erally if not always optimal. Indeed, one of the tenets of NI theory is that, for a given set of values that individuals hold, sometimes non- market institutions are more optimal (value-maximizing or, possibly, value-satisficing) than a market institution would be in that same situ- ation. In this respect, for NI theory a major focus is on the "ongoing process" in the evolution of values and beliefs, and the institutionaliz- ing of particular constellations of values, rather than on behavioral dy- namics of people within a particular set of market-oriented institutions [Gordon and Adams 1989, p. 98]. As technology changes and people acquire knowledge about the consequences of past or existing institu- tions, technologies, and individual and collective actions, beliefs and values change. This feedback can lead to institutional re-design [Gor- don and Adams 1989, pp. 17-67]. Some of the values Rokeach and others have identified as important in American society appear to be best achieved through or as a result This content downloaded from 128.227.197.233 on Mon, 05 Nov 2018 16:00:57 UTC
  • 17. All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms 1064 Gary D. Lynne and Jeffrey Burkhardt of maximizing behavior in markets: a comfortable life, family security, rational behavior, and others. Other values, however, are achieved in or institutionalized in different ways. As Rokeach indicates, when any values come to be institutionalized, particular institutions specialize in certain subsets of the larger set of "held values" [Rokeach 1979, pp. 50-53]. Another aspect of NI theory is that it accounts for the existence and function of a "community of interests," or "moral community," to use Buchanan's [1986] term. Moral community is the idea that in some sit- uations or with respect to some issue or problem, individuals feel them- selves to be members of an ongoing social enterprise, rather than "independent, isolated" maximizing individuals [Buchanan 1986, p. 109]. Mark Sagoff has also noted that rather than perceiving all situ- ations as opportunities for maximizing self-interest, individuals share a common concern, be it national pride, care for the environment, pub-
  • 18. lic health, or any other "social value" [Sagoff 1989] A. Alan Schmid also shows how mutual dependence and interdependence among indi- viduals underlies this notion of community [Schmid 1987, p. 27]. In- deed, recognition of interdependence seems the fundamental feature of moral community [Dallmayr 1978]. Moral communities can be both informally "institutionalized" or formally institutionalized through a political process. An important aspect of the latter case is this: Once a basic community value is institutionalized, individual and collective behavior comes to reflect it (see Gordon and Adams [1989, p. 7]). Moral community, institutionalized in law or policy, is in this respect self- reinforcing. A moral community can come into existence in any number of con- texts and for any number of reasons. Buchanan seems to think that reli- gion and a homogeneous cultural tradition underlay the most pervasive moral communities [Buchanan 1986, p. 109], although he admits that other manifestations or sources of community exist in trade unions, firms or social classes. What he does not explain is how a moral com- munity-and institutions that reflect it-can come into existence
  • 19. when hitherto there was none, and when in fact there had been only "moral order"-his term for the social situation wherein self-interested indi- viduals interact within the constraints of institutionalized civility, but without any common concern or value. An important question for NI theory is, however, when and how do widely shared purposes arise in the context of institutions and behaviors that aim at the maximization of individual wealth? How do institutions thereby change to reflect and embody these "new values?" This content downloaded from 128.227.197.233 on Mon, 05 Nov 2018 16:00:57 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms Evolution of Florida Water Institutions 1065 A number of reasons may explain why a group of individuals with different value priorities, different knowledge-levels, different work and lifestyles, might coalesce around a particular value or set of values so as to constitute a moral community with respect to a specific issue or problem. Certainly widespread perception of a "social crisis" could be one factor [Burkhardt 1988]. Increased knowledge about a
  • 20. situation where there already had been some degree of community would be an- other. Deliberate "contracting" for mutual defense or advantage would be a third. Strong charismatic leadership that brings about a coales- cence of values might be another [Buchholz, 1982]. The point is that moral communities can arise, and that institutions that reflect them can come to exist-or pass out of existence. Or, perhaps more relevant to the discussion below, the institutions can be created to reflect an emergent moral community, only to reinforce the notion of community and interdependence in the ongoing process of administering the value- mandate of the initial institutionalization. Through time, the dynamics of values and institutions are such that values that were once institutionalized can nevertheless change, forcing a de- or re-institutionalizing process. For example, some constellations of values in the southwestern United States led to the creation of pri- vate property rights in water that facilitated market processes (see Sa- liba [1987] for an overview of marketing in that area). Some led toward natural resource institutions that simulate market-like processes with taxes and subsidies (a vast literature exists here, see Baumol
  • 21. and Oates [1975]). We now see how these institutions change as a result of the ongoing valuing and institutionalizing process, to reflect the "cultural context" [Albelda, Gunn, and Waller 1987, p. 11]. In some cases, com- modities have been taken out of the market to reflect changed values (for instance, pesticides like DDT); in other cases, commodities have been returned to the market (saccharin, for example). In both kinds of circumstances (and others), NI addresses precisely the "institutionaliz- ing" game going on behind the market [Dugger 1988, p. 984], by looking at both the deliberate self-interested "contracting" activity of market participants and the historical evolution of the beliefs and values and moral communities that subsequently shape the institutions. It is to the evolution of Florida's water institution that we now turn. Florida's Evolution of the Rules of the Game Florida's early history of generally uncontrolled growth and un- guided natural resource use and development eventually led to consid- This content downloaded from 128.227.197.233 on Mon, 05 Nov 2018 16:00:57 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
  • 22. 1066 Gary D. Lynne and Jeffrey Burkhardt erable environmental stress (for overviews, see Blake [1980, esp. pp. 195-196] and Clark [1974, esp. pp. 43-46]). By 1970, population was doubling every twenty-five years statewide and doubling every fourteen years in seven south Florida counties [Blake 1980, p. 224]. Aquifers had been damaged by salt water intrusion from overpumping in coastal areas, development had occurred in important aquifer recharge areas, and water quality had notably worsened. Unprecedented droughts oc- curred in 1961, 1962, 1967, and again in 1970-1971 [Blake 1980, p. 224]. The droughts increased many citizens' awareness of the possibil- ity of long-term water shortages and further reductions in water quality, given the anticipated continued influx of people into the state- both permanent residents and tourists. Many people were in the process of questioning the values and belief systems that had encouraged rapid development. Even development interests were concerned, however, that water scarcity might affect their ability to attract new residents and businesses to the state. Everyone seems to have begun to question the processes by which resources, especially water, were allocated.
  • 23. By 1974, the general attitude in Florida toward resource use had changed [Blake 1980, p. 195]. Conservation and preservation became major political issues. By the mid- 1 970s the institutionalizing of a new set of values was well underway. The severe South Florida drought of 1970-1971 precipitated a series of political efforts to address these concerns and apparent new values [Clark 1974, p. 125]. In 1971, a special conference was organized by the governor to bring together both professional and lay people [Clark 1974, pp. 125-26] to address problems associated with uncontrolled growth and resource use. The conference served to highlight the need for reliable scientific and technical knowledge about the problems, but most importantly, it suggested that Floridans desired a long- term po- litical solution to those problems. The conference report laid the groundwork for dramatic institutional change. Subsequently, in 1972, four major pieces of land and water legislation were enacted [Clark 1974, pp. 126-36]. The law now more strictly regulated natural re- sources, provided for the purchase of environmentally sensitive lands, and mandated state-wide comprehensive planning. The Florida
  • 24. Water Resources Act ("the Act") focused on the regulation of well- drilling, surface water management, and consumptive use of water (see Tilley, Lynne, and Boggess [1985] for a discussion of the consumptive use por- tion].3 Commenting on this legislative activity the Governor noted that compared to other states Florida "would walk away with the honors" [Blake 1980, p. 223]. In fact, the legislation only started the process of This content downloaded from 128.227.197.233 on Mon, 05 Nov 2018 16:00:57 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms Evolution of Florida Water Institutions 1067 redirecting Florida's water institutions to reflect citizens' broader envi- ronmental concerns. The process has continued through administrative law in the water management districts put in place by the Act as well as in further growth management legislation during the 1 980s. The Florida Water Resources Act drew heavily on the Maloney Model Water Code [Maloney, Ausness, and Morris 1972]. The Code, intended for use in all of the eastern United States, has three purposes:
  • 25. to take into account the hydrologic interrelationship of all types of water resources in the state; to provide greater certainty than is possible under a court-administered reasonable use approach; yet to retain sufficient flex- ibility to make possible realistic long-range plans for the conservation and wise use of water resources and the elimination of waste [Maloney, Aus- ness, and Morris 1972, p. vii]. The Act incorporates all three purposes. A major assumption of the Act is that water administrative agencies need reliable knowledge about hy- drologic structures and patterns and other ecological relationships. To that end, professional staffs are charged with insuring that the lat- est information is used in advising the nine-member governing board in each district. The South Florida Water Management District, for ex- ample, employs more than 200 professionals (and over 1000 support employees), many with advanced degrees in the revelant academic dis- ciplines. The five districts regularly fund academic research at the state's universities in addition to using consulting firms. Board mem- bers appointed by the governor are also to be "experts on water" [Ma- loney, Ausness, and Morris 1972, p. 79]. Although the possibility of
  • 26. electing the boards is now being considered, the original reason for ap- pointing the board members was to insure that such individuals had the necessary understanding of the hydrologic system. The point of assembling all this expertise is planning, and indeed, planning represents a key feature of the Act. The State Department of Environmental Regulation has been charged with coordinating plan- ning in the five water districts that encompass the state.4 However, the water districts themselves, not the state, do most of the planning. This structure is meant to insure that regional differences in both hydrology and values are adequately reflected in the process. Once in place, the Act facilitated the evolution of a process for deter- mining both the value of water and its appropriate uses. Notably, the process facilitated by the Act fits John Commons's account of evolving reasonable value: Commons showed how value evolves through politi- cal negotiation in addition to market process [Gruchy 1972, p. 42]. As This content downloaded from 128.227.197.233 on Mon, 05 Nov 2018 16:00:57 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
  • 27. 1068 Gary D. Lynne and Jeffrey Burkhardt Commons noted, "Reasonable value changes with new combinations of circumstances and collective control, and is in process of evolution through changes in efficiency, scarcity, custom, politics, and dominant interests" [Commons 1934, p. 207]. In concordance with Florida's Ad- ministrative Procedure Act,5 the Act facilitates handling new circum- stances and changing values through negotiation and the use of forms of nonmarket interaction among those with varying interests, such as public meetings, hearings and workshops. Over and above the question of valuation, however, the Act also forces the districts to decide what the reasonable uses of water are for their areas. The districts are not without guidance on this question, however. Certain standards of rea- sonableness were incorporated into the institution reflecting a range of values associated with water. For example, individuals do not need per- mits to take water for domestic purposes [Maloney, Ausness, and Mor- ris 1972, p. 177], reflecting the primacy of individual rights to this needed resource.6 Private land may be condemned, however,
  • 28. for con- servation purposes [Maloney, Ausness, and Morris 1972, p. 148]. Moreover, transport across hydrologic boundaries (interdistrict trans- fer) is not permitted unless demonstrated to be in the public interest.7 Users may not cause an "unmitigated adverse impact" on other users, defined in one district as a decrease of 10 percent or more in the with- drawal capability [South Florida Water Management District 1985, p. B-6]. The standard of reasonableness was supplemented with the concept of beneficial use, reflecting the Maloney reasonable beneficial use stan- dard [Maloney, Capehart, and Hoofman 1979]. As defined by Maloney et al., the reasonable beneficial standard refers to: "The use of water in such quantity as is necessary for economic and efficient utilization for a purpose and in a manner which is both reasonable and consistent with the public interest."8 The beneficial use component refers primar- ily to the private interest (benefits and costs) in water, reasonableness involves the relationship of the private to the public interest. The stan- dard suggests economic efficiency can be pursued only in the larger con-
  • 29. text of also satisfying the public interest. A main component of that public interest that underlies the admin- istrative structure is the value Floridians placed on what can be referred to as "the continuity of human life" [Tool, 1986, esp. p. 50, 57- 58]. The Act expresses overriding concerns for wise use of water to insure the continuity of human life with the focus on public health, safety, and general welfare [Maloney, Ausness, and Morris 1972, p. 277, 279].9 Both the Code and the Act also emphasize the continuity of life in fish, This content downloaded from 128.227.197.233 on Mon, 05 Nov 2018 16:00:57 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms Evolution of Florida Water Institutions 1069 wildlife, and other natural systems [Maloney, Ausness, and Morris 1972, p. 277].10 The long-term integrity of all water and related resource systems should be protected in all phases of the hydrologic cycle [Ma- loney, Ausness, and Morris 1972, p. 82]. Despite the recognition of eco- nomic efficiency in the goals of the Code and Act, the logical inference
  • 30. is that other values and perhaps even a "moral community" with re- spect to water operated to produce an institutional structure that re- flects those more fundamental values. The important point is that Floridans established an administrative, rather than a market, structure for the determination of water alloca- tion and use. It is with respect to this outcome that NC theory provides little guidance. Indeed, NC theory may even hold that Floridans were (and continue to be) mistaken if not unreasonable in their institution- alizing process. NC theory maintains that whatever problems exist in allocation/use/valuation, laws should be enacted to remove impedi- ments to the natural evolution of water (and other environmental re- source) markets. Alternatively, taxes and subsidies should be enacted to emulate "natural" markets. Under these market or quasi- market ar- rangements the optimal long-run use would have been achieved. Pop- ulation growth, droughts, and the like would have only affected the relative prices of alternative uses. For NI theory, to the contrary, the administrative structure put in place in Florida has an inherent reasonableness, given the desires and
  • 31. values of the population. Interestingly, many of the Rokeach values can be seen to have been specifically institutionalized in the Act and in ad- ministrative rules and regulations developed by each water district since 1972 [Rokeach 1973, p. 28]. Uncertainty has been reduced (and security enhanced): permits can be issued for up to twentyi years and the original permit holder will be given first consideration for renewal. I ' Permit holders are expected to be obedient: water districts have police power to enforce rules.'2 Applicants should be honest: permits can be lost if false information has been used to get the permit.'3 Applicants should be ambitious and hard working: permits can be lost for nonuse of water.14 Individual permit holders are encouraged to be independent: only minimal efforts are put into directing actual on-site water using practices. More to the point is whether or not a moral community in the sense discussed above exists with respect to the allocation and use of this re- source. The idea of such a community of shared purposes is arguably apparent in the code that underlies the Act. The swiftness with which the state moved from initial identification of those problems to an in-
  • 32. This content downloaded from 128.227.197.233 on Mon, 05 Nov 2018 16:00:57 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms 1070 Gary D. Lynne and Jeffrey Burkhardt stitutional structure that addresses them suggests at least some measure of "shared purpose." The continuation of the mandate of the Act in the administrative activities of the water districts suggests some degree of continued commitment, as does the surprisingly small number of legal challenges to decisions of the water districts' boards. The problem is that even with this institutional structure in place and continuing its function, there remains conflict and competition over water in Florida. This may suggest that either (1) no moral community ever existed, the Act instead reflecting a somewhat accidental confluence of self- interested and environmental considerations; or (2) a community did exist, but no longer does: the institutional structure no longer reflects the values of Floridians with respect to water; or (3) the community still exists and the institutional structure continues to reflect it, but that fine tuning and "reinstitutionalizing" will be a continual
  • 33. activity. We favor the last explanation, but also realize further study of the matter is needed. Floridians Have Yet to Address Competition While the code and the Act give a workable framework within which to reduce conflict, problems remain. An especially difficult one is re- solving competition, especially during droughts. Consumptive use permits currently specify an upper limit on with- drawals for some drought frequency, such as: "draw up to one acre inch per day on average given a rainfall year described by a 2-in- 10 drought frequency."'5 As long as 2-in-O0, or wetter, rainfall years occur, the user can draw the one acre inch. If rainfall has been lower, however, the permit now only gives rights to participate in a process for allocating water (a competition) defined by provisions of a water shortage plan put in place by each water management district.'6 The "competition," however, has some very stringent and limiting rules, especially when compared to the rules underlying market com- petition. For example, after the South Florida Water Management Dis- trict declares a moderate, severe, extreme, or critical water
  • 34. shortage, suggesting the need for up to a 15, 30, 45, or 60 percent reduction in overall demand, a listing of priority areas and particular allocations to each class of user comes into force [South Florida Water Management District, 1982, p. 5 and Figure 21-1]. At the 45 percent level, for exam- ple, overhead agricultural sprinklers can only be operated from 7 p.m. to 7 a.m., while low-volume agricultural irrigation systems can be op- erated without limit; domestic use is limited to 40 gallons per person This content downloaded from 128.227.197.233 on Mon, 05 Nov 2018 16:00:57 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms Evolution of Florida Water Institutions 1071 per day; and swimming pools in tourist hotels cannot be filled. Alloca- tion is by specific limits for each use in the district, with all restrictions centrally determined and made a part of the water shortage rule. The problem faced by water users in such a system can be highlighted with an excerpt from one such water shortage plan as pertaining to ag- riculture during a 45 percent shortfall: "The share of the total
  • 35. agricul- tural irrigation allocation available to each user will be based on any prioritization among crops the District establishes based on economic loss or equity considerations and the acreage and quantity of withdraw- als for which the user has been permitted" [South Florida Water Man- agement District 1982, p. 20]. Generally each class of water user can be subjected to a priortization and allocation process defined in detail by the district during each drought event. While such a process must comply with the Act (with the possibility of various kinds of negoti- ation and interaction, and in this sense, a process generating reasonable value as argued earlier in the case of evolving rules), we question the effectiveness of such a process for allocating water among private sector uses, both during droughts and over the long run. The problem really is an information problem. Reliable hydrologic and value information about every gallon of water must be available to the forty-five people (five water districts, nine governing board mem- bers in each) charged with all the permit and water allocation decisions for the entire state. As noted, the boards do employ large, well- trained professional staffs to help the information problem. Much of
  • 36. the $150 million spent each year for water management by the five districts is to generate information [Lynne 1988, p. 95]. Even so, it appears impos- sible for the boards and staffs to know how much water each use should have at all times [Lynne 1988, pp. 99-100]. Reliable knowledge gener- ated through research can provide a portion of the needed information, and public hearing processes can to some extent facilitate determining how much to allocate to each user. Practically speaking, however, use- ful information will always be in short supply if the only way for indi- viduals to interact is through the present political process. Public meetings and hearings, workshops, and other means of getting informa- tion to forty-five board members appear inadequate for their task of allocating billions of gallons of water to millions of users. In the eyes of some observers, water or water rental markets may represent a better way for allocating this resource, especially within the private sector. As NC theory holds, individuals selling or rent- ing water would not do so unless a benefit was expected, and the buy- ers and renters would not want water unless a gain was expected.
  • 37. This content downloaded from 128.227.197.233 on Mon, 05 Nov 2018 16:00:57 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms 1072 Gary D. Lynne and Jeffrey Burkhardt Because both individuals gain, economic efficiency occurs. Both the competition-during-drought and information problems would be obvi- ated. During droughts, prices would simply rise: holders of excess water would eventually sell. No state- or district-wide information about value regarding private uses would be necessary, and information would be needed only about hydrology and the values pertaining to the public interest, both of which would still be the charge of the districts. As severe as these (and other) problems might be for the administra- tion of Florida's water policy, the fact is that Floridians would probably not tolerate a free market to resolve all the water allocation decisions. James Swaney [1988, p. 36] has noted the "shortsightedness" of water markets; markets may miss major value shifts, which seemingly is a major reason for the Act. The Florida community may favor relatively free water marketing or renting during short term droughts
  • 38. (when val- ues are stable) but only a very limited marketing for long-term alloca- tion, when values are shifting. Information about market prices for short-term water might prove especially helpful to the boards during droughts. Some limited marketing for long-term allocation may also provide insights into which uses might be encouraged and which should be discontinued, but only if major value changes can be insti- tutionalized in other processes. Some marketing may also be a way to control those rent- seekers who remain. Individuals who would otherwise obtain resources by putting obstacles in the way of markets would now have to buy water from other people. The net result would be a sharing of the rent. Basic admin- istrative structures, however, would still be needed to insure that other values were considered: administrative and board review would still be needed to monitor transactions and to influence the direction of wa- ter markets. Indeed, not only is water "different" in the eyes of Florid- ians, it is too important to be left to the market. As Swaney has noted, society will not normally let such an important resource be allocated by the "Juggernaut market" [Swaney 1988, fn. 35, p. 43]. Yet,
  • 39. "properly administered water trading (could represent) an instrumental institu- tional adjustment" [Swaney 1988, p. 44]. The current institutional structure probably needs only some fine tuning, possibly involving some marketing, to further insure that it both reflects the community's (moral) evaluation and the desires for its economic and efficient use. The evolution of water markets in Florida would depend on a num- ber of considerations in addition to their information- transmission or efficiency-preserving functions: (1) Water markets will arise only if the other values Floridians hold (most importantly, the "continuity of This content downloaded from 128.227.197.233 on Mon, 05 Nov 2018 16:00:57 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms Evolution of Florida Water Institutions 1073 life") are secured. (2) Unconstrained "free" markets in the sense of the NC (seemingly immaculate) conception will arise only if people gener- ally believe either that there are no rent-seekers left in Florida or that
  • 40. the nature of the resource is such that rent-seeking is minimized. How- ever, (3) water markets may never evolve if the community's values associated with the water resource can be satisfied within some form of political/administrative process. The implication is that (4) water markets will arise, once the administrative structure has done its job of reinforcing in attitudes and behavior the idea that water allocation and use is a matter of community values. The question is whether the insti- tutional structure will reinforce that moral community, or fall prey to the "wealth maximization" model in its basic allocation decisions. Conclusions and Implications Florida's water institutions originally evolved in a setting of fear and concern arising from water scarcity caused by rampant economic devel- opment. Fear and concern appears to have led to a coalescence of atti- tudes in the late 1960s among economic development interests and environmental preservation communities of the state, given the general support for a dramatically different water institution starting in 1972. The 1972 Florida Water Resources Act (and the rules, regulations, cus- toms, and habits that have evolved since 1972) seemingly
  • 41. reflect that coalescence, which we have referred to as a moral community. The Act institutionalized the community's values and put in place a process for drawing out the practical implications of those values, as reliable knowledge about both the hydrologic system and the impacts of growth, development, and conservation has become available. The ad- ministrative requirements imposed by the later institutions have changed behavior, but those institutions already reflected a changed at- titude toward water resources. The institutions usually have served to reduce conflict. However, as conflict erupts again in the face of institu- tional rigidities (which may be a constant, under Veblen's notion that "whatever is, is wrong"), institutional adjustment will generally be needed. Both during and after adjustment, markets may serve a useful role, mainly because of the information transmission capability of mar- kets. As we suggested, however, the nature of those markets may be decidedly different from the market models proposed by neoclassical theory, dependent as they are on the existence of a moral community. Colorado, New Mexico, and other western U.S. water markets appar- ently function within the context of a moral community: in nearly all
  • 42. This content downloaded from 128.227.197.233 on Mon, 05 Nov 2018 16:00:57 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms 1074 Gary D. Lynne and Jeffrey Burkhardt cases, state and federal agencies administer both the market and the prices (see Saliba [1987]). Markets may eventually emerge in Florida. Although the Florida Water Resources Act developed rules to reflect an administrative re- sponse to moral community, market-like institutions are not necessar- ily inconsistent with its intent. Frank J. Trelease has argued that If an easterner wants the best of water use laws, he could make no better start than first considering the provisions of the Model Code for planning, regulating and protecting water resources. But he should think very hard before he adopts the Code's system for distributing and redistributing the water allocated to the private sector [Trelease 1974, p. 213]. Trelease favors water rental markets, as well as sales of water and sales of water rights, for allocating water that has been set aside for the pri-
  • 43. vate sector [Trelease 1974, esp. pp. 222-223]. His point may have some validity: such administered markets may prove to be a good way to meet peoples' differing, secondary needs and values in the private sec- tor once basic "continuity of life" values are imbedded in the institu- tion reflecting the public interest. Even so, some evidence exists for thinking that in many states, including Florida, an extensive marketing structure will never emerge. Susan C. Nunn suggests that High Plains (particularly west Texas) farmers would not be favorably disposed toward water markets, or any other sort of institutional change that might affect distribution, no mat- ter how economically efficient [Nunn 1985, pp. 890-91]. As noted ear- lier, Shabman and Cox also seem to believe markets may not be politically tractable in Virginia [Shabman and Cox 1986, p. 165]. One thing is clear: the evolution or lack of evolution of markets (or any other set of institutional arrangements) is better explained through NI analysis than through NC theory. This is particularly true with re- spect to water institutions. This is because NI theory provides a more empirical and realistic explanation of the emergence of institutions on the basis of individual and community values, and the
  • 44. institutional conditions under which people acquire, maintain, or change their val- ues and subsequent actions. In the case of Florida's water institutions, NI analysis provides the basis for an explanation of the conditions un- der which the non-market institutions evolved and will be maintained, insofar as they achieve values and objectives not easily reached with markets. This content downloaded from 128.227.197.233 on Mon, 05 Nov 2018 16:00:57 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms Evolution of Florida Water Institutions 1075 Notes 1. Rokeach calls them instrumental values, but uses the terminology some- what differently than in NI theory. That is, Rokeach's use suggests "func- tion" or "means" or "mode of operation," such as "being honest" or "being capable" or "being intellectucal." While NI instrumental value theory might suggest that people pursue Rokeach instrumental values, clearly NI instrumental valuation has more referential content than simply describing a list of objectives.
  • 45. 2. This is not to suggest that Buchanan and other Public Choice (PC) theorists (such as Tullock) are neoclassical economists. As correctly pointed out by an anonymous referee, NC theorists "consider institutional adjustment to be outside the domain of economics. PC theorists investigate choice of in- stitutions using NC assumptions about maximizing individuals." We do believe, however, that differences often are blurred because of the insis- tence of the PC theorists on individuals only seeking self- interest with little regard for or influence from the community, as in the NC theory. 3. Florida Statutes, Chapter 373. 4. Ibid., Chapter 373.036. 5. Ibid., Chapter 120.52. 6. Ibid., Chapter 373.219. 7. Ibid., Chapter 373.2295(10). 8. Ibid., Chapter 373.019(4). 9. Ibid., Chapter 373.016(h). 10. Ibid., Chapter 373.016(e). 11. Ibid., Chapters 373.236(1) and 373.233(2). 12. Ibid., Chapters 373,603. 13. Ibid., Chapter 373.243(1). 14. Ibid., Chapter 373.243(4). 15. A maximum day withdrawal is also generally specified, but is not necessary to the example being discussed. 16. Florida Administrative Code, Chap. 40.
  • 46. References Albelda, Randy, Christopher Gunn, and William Waller, ed. 1987. Alternatives to Economic Orthodoxy. Armonk, N.Y.: M. E. Sharpe, Inc. Anderson, Terry L. 1983. Ending the Policy Drought. Baltimore: The Johns Hopkins University Press. Baumol, William J. and Wallace E. Oates. 1975. The Theory of Environmental Policy. Englewood Cliffs, N.J.: Prentice Hall, Inc. Blake, Nelson M. 1980. Land into Water- Water into Land, A History of Water Management in Florida. Tallahassee,: University Presses of Florida. Brown, Lee, Brian McDonald, John Tysseling, and Charles DuMars. 1982. "Water Reallocation, Market Proficiency, and Conflicting Social Values." In This content downloaded from 128.227.197.233 on Mon, 05 Nov 2018 16:00:57 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms 1076 Gary D. Lynne and Jeffrey Burkhardt Water and Agriculture in the Western U.S.: Conservation, Reallocation, and Markets, ed. Gary D. Weatherford (Charles W. Howe, General
  • 47. Editor), pp. 191-255. Boulder, Colo.: Studies in Water Policy and Management, No. 2, Westview Press, Inc. Buchanan, James M. 1986. Liberty, Market, and State: Political Economy in the 1980's. London: Wheatsheaf Books LTD, Harvester Press Publishing Group. . 1987. "The Constitution of Economic Policy." American Economic Review 77 (June): 243-50. Buchanan, James M. and Gordon Tullock. 1967. The Calculus of Consent. Ann Arbor, Mich.: University of Michigan Press [1962]. Buchholz, Rogene. 1982. Business Environment and Public Policy. Englewood Cliffs, N.J.: Prentice-Hall. Burkhardt, Jeffrey. 1988. "Crisis, Argument, and Agriculture." Journal of Ag- ricultural Ethics. 1 (Summer): 123-38. Caldwell, Bruce. 1982. Beyond Positivism, Economic Methodology in the Twen- tieth Century. London: George Allen and Unwin. Clark, Luther J. 1974. The Florida Experience, Land and Water Policy in a Growth State. Baltimore and London: Published for Resources for the Fu- ture, Inc. by Johns Hopkins University Press.
  • 48. Commons, John R. 1934. Institutional Economics: Its Place in Political Econ- omy. Madison: University of Wisconsin Press. Dallmayr, Fred, ed. 1978. From Contract to Community. New York: Marcel Dekker. Downs, Anthony. 1957. An Economic Theory of Democracy. New York: Har- per and Brothers. Dugger, William M. 1988. "A Research Agenda for Institutional Economics." Journal of Economic Issues 22 (December): 983-1002. Gardner, B. Delworth. 1983. "Water Pricing and Rent Seeking in California Agriculture." In Water Rights, Scarce Resource Allocation, Bureacracy, and the Environment, ed. Terry L. Anderson, pp. 83-115. San Francisco: Pacific Institute for Public Policy Research. Gordon, Wendell and John Adams. 1989. Economics as Social Science. River- dale, Md.: The Riverdale Company. Gruchy, Allan G. 1972. Contemporary Economic Thought: The Contribution of Neo-Institutional Economics. Clifton, N.J.: Augustus M. Kelley. Hodgson, Geoffrey M. 1988. Economics and Institutions. Philadelphia: Univer-
  • 49. sity of Pennsylvania Press. Howe, Charles W., Dennis R. Schurmeier, and W. Douglas Shaw, Jr. 1986. "In- novative Approaches to Water Allocation: The Potential for Water Mar- kets." Water Resources Research 22 (April): 439-45. Lynne, Gary D. 1988. "Agricultural Water Modeling and Economic Informa- tion Needs Under the Model Water Code." Water Resources Bulletin 24 (February): 95-101 . McPherson, Michael S. 1984. "Limits on Self-Seeking, The Role of Morality in Economic Life." In Neoclassical Political Economy, The Analysis of Rent- Seeking and DUP Activities. ed. David C. Colander, pp. 71-85. Cambridge, Mass." Ballinger Publishing Company. Maloney, Frank E., Richard C. Ausness, and J. Scott Morris. 1972. A Model This content downloaded from 128.227.197.233 on Mon, 05 Nov 2018 16:00:57 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms Evolution of Florida Water Institutions 1077 Water Code With Commentary. Gainesville, Fla.: University of Florida Press.
  • 50. Maloney, Frank E., Lynne C. Capehart, and Robert S. Hoofman. 1979. "Flor- ida's 'Reasonable Beneficial' Water Use Standard: Have East and West Met?" University of Florida Law Review 31 (Winter): 253-83. Nunn, Susan C. 1985. "The Political Economy of Institutional Change: A Dis- tribution Criterion for Acceptance of Groundwater Rules." Natural Re- sources Journal 25 (October): 867-92. Rokeach, Milton. 1973. The Nature of Human Values. New York: The Free Press. . 1979. "From Individual to Institutional Values: With Special Refer- ence to the Values of Science." In Understanding Human Values, Individual and Societal. Ed. Milton Rokeach, pp. 47-70. New York: The Free Press. Sagoff, Mark. 1989. The Economy of the Earth. New York: Cambridge Univer- sity Press. Saliba, Bonnie C. 1987. Water Markets in Theory and Practice. Boulder and London: Westview Press. Schmid, A. Alan. 1987. Property, Power, and Public Choice: An Inquiry into Law and Economics. New York: Praeger Publishers (second edition).
  • 51. Shabman, Leonard and William E. Cox. 1986. "Costs of Water Management Institutions: The Case of Southeastern Virginia." In Scarce Water and Insti- tutional Change. Ed. Kenneth D. Frederick, pp. 134-70, Washington, D.C.: Resources for the Future. South Florida Water Management District. 1985. "Basis of Review for Water Use Permit Applications Within the South Florida Water Management Dis- trict." West Palm Beach, Fla. Resource Control Department, January. South Florida Water Management District. 1982. "Water Shortage Plan, Rules of the South Florida Water Management District, Chapter 40E- 21." West Palm Beach, Fla.; May 1982. Swaney, James A. 1988. "Trading Water: Market Extension, Social Improve- ment, or What?" Journal of Economic Issues 22 (March): 33- 48. Tilley, Marsha, Gary D. Lynne, and William G. Boggess. 1985. Florida Water Management District Rules and Regulations: Consumptive Use Permits. Florida Agricultural Experiment Station Circular S-317. Gainesville, Fla. University of Florida. Tool, Marc R. 1986. Essays in Social Value Theory: A
  • 52. Neoinstitutionalist Con- tribution. Armonk, N.Y.: M. E. Sharpe, Inc. Trelease, Frank J. 1974. "The Model Water Code, The Wise Administrator and the Goddam Bureaucrat." Natural Resources Journal 14 (April): 207-29. Wandschneider, Philip R. 1986. "Neoclassical and Institutionalist Explana- tions of Changes in Northwest Water Institutions." Journal of Economic Is- sues 20 (March): 87-107. This content downloaded from 128.227.197.233 on Mon, 05 Nov 2018 16:00:57 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms Contents105910601061106210631064106510661067106810691 0701071107210731074107510761077Issue Table of ContentsJournal of Economic Issues, Vol. 24, No. 4 (Dec., 1990), pp. 963-1241Front MatterNew Light on John Dewey, Clarence Ayres, and the Development of Evolutionary Economics [pp. 963-979]"New Thinking" in the Soviet Economy: Lessons for Western Political Economists [pp. 981- 994]The Causes of Black Poverty: Evidence and Interpretation [pp. 995-1016]The Rhetoric of Inquiry or the Sophistry of the Status Quo? Exploring the Common Ground between Critical Rhetoric and Institutional Economics [pp. 1017-1026]Why Johnny (Ph.D., Economics) Can't Read: A Rhetorical Analysis of Thorstein Veblen and a Response to Donald McCloskey's "Rhetoric of Economics" [pp. 1027-1044]Retirement as an Institution [pp. 1045-1057]The Evolution of Water Institutions in Florida: A Neoinstitutionalist Perspective [pp. 1059- 1077]Client Consumption Patterns within an Income-Based Energy Assistance Program [pp. 1079-1093]Institutional Adjustment, Instrumental Efficiency, and Reasonable Value [pp.
  • 53. 1095-1107]Notes and CommunicationsInstrumental Value an Eternal Verity? A Reply to Wendell Gordon [pp. 1109- 1122]Culture versus Social Value? A Response to Anne Mayhew [pp. 1122-1133]Economic Reforms in Socialist Economics: A Comment on Petr [pp. 1133-1137]Review: Keynesianism, Monetarism, and the Crisis of the State: A Review Article [pp. 1139-1146]Book ReviewsReview: Two Reviews of William M. Dugger: "Corporate Hegemony" [pp. 1147-1155]Review: untitled [pp. 1157-1163]Review: untitled [pp. 1163-1166]Review: untitled [pp. 1166-1168]Review: untitled [pp. 1168-1172]Review: untitled [pp. 1172- 1175]Review: untitled [pp. 1175-1179]Review: untitled [pp. 1179-1181]Review: untitled [pp. 1181-1186]Review: untitled [pp. 1186-1189]Review: untitled [pp. 1190-1193]Review: untitled [pp. 1193-1196]Review: untitled [pp. 1196- 1197]Review: untitled [pp. 1198-1199]Author Index: Volumes I - XXIV (1967-1990) [pp. 1201-1241]Back Matter