SlideShare a Scribd company logo
1 of 25
Download to read offline
Estimating the Causal Effect of Social Capital: A Review of Recent Research
Author(s): Ted Mouw
Source: Annual Review of Sociology, Vol. 32 (2006), pp. 79-102
Published by: Annual Reviews
Stable URL: http://www.jstor.org/stable/29737732 .
Accessed: 28/07/2014 10:50
Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available at .
http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp
.
JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide range of
content in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and facilitate new forms
of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact support@jstor.org.
.
Annual Reviews is collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend access to Annual Review of
Sociology.
http://www.jstor.org
This content downloaded from 205.213.172.3 on Mon, 28 Jul 2014 10:50:23 AM
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
Annu. Rev. Sociol. 2006. 32:79-102
doi: 10.1146/annurev.soc.32.061604.123150
Copyright? 2006 byAnnual Reviews. All rightsreserved
First published online as aReview inAdvance onApril 6, 2006
Estimating the Causal Effect of Social
CAPITAL: A Review ofRecent Research
TedMouw
Department of Sociology, University ofNorth Carolina, Chapel Hill,
North Carolina 27599; email: tedmouw@email.unc.edu
Key Words peer effects, social networks, social homophily, fixed effects models
? Abstract Although thereisa largeliteratureon social capital,empirical estimates
of theeffectof social capitalmay be biased because of social homophily, thetendency
of similarpeople tobecome friendswith each other.Despite themethodological dif?
ficulties, a recent literature has emerged across several different disciplines that tries
to estimate the causal effect of social capital. This paper reviews this recent empiri?
cal literature on social capital, paying close attention to the statistical and theoretical
assumptions involved. Overall, there is evidence that genuine progress has been made
in estimating the effect of social capital. The reviewed articles should provide useful
examples for future research.
INTRODUCTION
The purpose of this review is to examine recent attempts to estimate the causal
effectof social capital. As a number of recent authors have pointed out, there is a
considerable amount of ambiguity regarding theprecise definitionof social capital
(Portes 1998, Fischer 2005, Manski 2000, Kadushin 2004). The literaturethat I
review focuses on what we
might call "network" social capital, i.e., the effect of
characteristics of friends, acquaintances,
or groups on individual outcomes. Portes
(1998) provides a useful definition of this form of social capital as "the ability
of actors to secure benefits by virtue of theirmembership in social networks or
other social structures," stressing that whereas "economic capital is in people's
bank accounts and human capital is inside theirheads, social capital inheres in the
structureof theirrelationships" (p. 7). The key concept here is thatsocial capital
is not an individual characteristic or a personality traitbut a resource thatresides
in thenetworks and groups towhich people belong.
The focus on network social capital in this review is not intended to dismiss
alternative definitions of social capital that stress the importance either of norms
and values or of group-level outcomes. Fukuyama (1999, p. 16), for instance, pro?
vides a coherent definition of social capital thatemphasizes the role of norms on
group outcomes. Instead, thereason I focus on network social capital isbecause, as
discussed below, theproblem of causality fornetwork social capital isparticularly
0360-0572/06/0811-0079$20.00 79
This content downloaded from 205.213.172.3 on Mon, 28 Jul 2014 10:50:23 AM
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
80 MOUW
clear, and it taps into an existing literatureon the role of endogenous friendship
formation and self-selection in the estimation of peer effects. In addition, as re?
viewed here, there is a growing body of research on network social capital and
peer effects thattakes theproblem of endogeneity seriously and, I believe, makes
progress inestimating the trueeffectof social capital.
The papers covered in thisreview indicate thatgenuine progress can bemade in
estimating thecausal effectof social capital. Although many of thepapers referto
the estimation of peer effects, social interactions,or some formof neighborhood
effectswithout explicit reference tosocial capital,most of thesewould be subsumed
under the definition of social capital by Portes (1998) referred to above. All,
however, areuseful because theypresent creativeways ofdealing with thequestion
of causality under endogenous social interaction and can serve as useful examples
forfutureresearch on social capital.
A fundamental challenge in the estimation of the effect of social capital is
posed by thecentral fact thatindividuals choose who theywant tobe friendswith
andwhat groups theywant tojoin.Why does thismatter? The principle of social
homophily argues thatpeople tend to choose otherswho are similar to them as
friends.As a result, it is quite possible thatmuch of theestimated effectof social
capital simply reflects selection effectsbased on themyriad of nonrandom ways
inwhich people become friends.
Of course, estimating a causal effect is difficult, ifnot impossible, with the
kind of nonexperimental data thatmost social scientistswork with ingeneral, so
this sortof problem is endemic in the social sciences. Given thegeneral nature of
thisproblem, why shouldwe be concerned about thecausality of social capital in
particular? Three reasons: First, as mentioned above, social homophily suggests
a competing explanation of the social capital findings. Second, it is time; in the
past decade therehas been an enormous outpouring of empirical studies on the
effectof social capital on a variety of outcomes. At thispoint in thematuration
of the social capital literature,it isworthwhile to ask whether we can adjudicate
between alternative theories thatare also consistentwith much of the same evi?
dence. As it stands,much of the literatureresorts to asserting by fiat,or by faith,
thatestimates of theeffectof social capital are correctby ignoringorminimizing
thepotential problems posed by nonrandom friendship formation.Third, thevery
name social capital invitesa comparison to thehuman capital literature.Although
some scholars have argued thatthetermsocial capital iscounterproductive because
social capital is not really capital at all (Fischer 2005), thepopularity of the term
is likelydue, at least inpart, to theequivalence thatitsuggestswith other formsof
capital.
Posing questions about causality should not be construed as picking on social
capital unfairly,
as the same
questions have been raised regarding human capital.
Justas one can argue thatestimates of theeffectof social capital arebiased because
of social homophily, one can argue thatestimates of the effectof human capital
onwages are biased because of unobserved factors thataffect schooling and labor
market productivity (e.g., ifsmarterworkers earnmore and find iteasier to succeed
This content downloaded from 205.213.172.3 on Mon, 28 Jul 2014 10:50:23 AM
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
CAUSAL EFFECTS OF SOCIAL CAPITAL 81
in school, then the correlation between education and earnings will partly reflect
higherpay thatisdue tohighernatural ability).Economists have taken thisquestion
seriously; a recent review of the causal effect of education on earnings has a
bibliography listing several pages of attempts toestimate the trueeffectof human
capital (Card 1999; see also Card 2001).
By arguing thatsocial capital needs to confront theproblem posed by friend?
ship choice, I am not arguing thatconcerns about causality should induce research
paralysis, where one avoids tacklingany subject thatgoes beyond a simple descrip?
tive analysis. At the same time, I am also not advocating turningto complicated
statisticalmodels, such as structuralequations, as a solution for the lack of exper?
imental data. As we shall see, these models make strong assumptions that cannot
be tested,and theymay provide misleading estimates.Many of themost interest?
ing studies reviewed below use fairly simplemethods combined with innovative
use of quasi-experimental data. Researchers should be carefulwith the statistical
assumptions theymake inestimating theeffectof social capital, and these assump?
tions should bemade transparentto thereader, so he or she can decide thevalidity
of the technique.
In thenext section, I provide a brief overview of why nonrandom friendship
acquisition may bias social capital models before I turnto a review of the recent
literature.
THE BASICPROBLEM
Sobel (1995) andWinship & Sobel (2004) provide useful discussions of causality
in the social sciences. Ideally, an experimental approach tocausality is preferable,
manipulating one variable while holding everything else constant.When this is
not possible, natural experiments and quasi-experiments provide
an alternative
approach. In all the literaturediscussed below, a careful understanding of the
assumptions involved ineachmodeling approach iscritical, as is an understanding
of thecontingent and restrictednature of the resultingcausal claims. Nonetheless,
many of thepapers discussed representa substantial improvement in theestimation
of theeffectof social capital.
A fundamental claim of the social capital literature is that the characteristics
and resources of friends,contacts, and groupsmay affect individual outcomes. For
example,
a
positive correlation between the average characteristics of one's friends
and some individual outcome is interpretedas evidence of the effect of social
capital. However, because, for the most part, individuals choose their friends and
thegroups theybelong to, some, ifnot all, of thepositive correlationmay simply
be due to thefact thatsimilar people tend to associate with one another.There is
a large literatureon theprinciple of social homophily (seeMcPherson et al. 2001
fora review), suggestingmany dimensions along which individuals with similar
characteristics socialize with each other.As a result,despite the strong intuitive
appeal of the importance of social capital, skepticismmay exert itsown appeal,
This content downloaded from 205.213.172.3 on Mon, 28 Jul 2014 10:50:23 AM
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
82 MOUW
particularly for those inclined to attribute social behavior to individual choice
ratherthan to social interaction (forexample, Manski 1993, pp. 531-32).
Clear evidence on the role of homophily comes from longitudinal research on
adolescent friendships. Kandel (1978) and Cohen (1977) use longitudinal data
on adolescent friendships to show thatmuch of the similarity in attitudes and
behavior among friendsorwithin cliques isdue tofriendship choice ratherthan to
peer effects.Kandel (1978), for instance, studies thechange in similarity in best
friends' attitudes and behavior at thebeginning and end of the school year and
finds thatabout half of the increase in similarity is due to adolescents changing
friendsduring thecourse of theyear ratherthan adapting theirbehavior/attitudes
to resemble their initial friend.Cohen (1977, p. 237) concludes thatmost of the
similarity in adolescents' attitudes isdue to initialhomophilic selection.
Explicit depiction of theestimation problem posed by individual choice extends
back toBlalock (1984) in sociology.Writing about contextual effects?the effect
of aggregate group variables on individual outcomes?Blalock notes that "it is
indeed possible thatpersons will select theircontexts on thebasis of theirown
preferences" making the direction of causation difficult to determine (Blalock
1984, p. 369). Blalock stresses the importance of careful theoretical consideration
to account for the relationship between individual- and group-level variables. In
thecase of social capital, thispoints to the importance of a detailed understanding
of how individuals choose their friends as a precursor to estimating empirical
models on the effectof friends' characteristics with nonexperimental data. In a
studyof theeffectof peer influences on occupational and educational aspirations,
Duncan et al. (1968) recognize theproblem posed by the self-selection of friends
by arguing that"if assortment on thebasis of aspirations proves tobe important,
our estimates of themutual influenceof friendson each other's aspirations are not
merely wrong; theybecome irrelevant" (p. 135). As discussed by Friedkin (1990),
theflip side of a concern about therole of unmeasured individual characteristics on
social capital effects is the impact thatunmeasured network factorsmay have on
estimates of theeffectof individual variables. Although he largelyassumes thatthe
networks of friends and peers are exogenous, he also considers the implications
of the networks themselves being endogenous to individual characteristics and
preferences (Friedkin 1990, Figure 5, p. 325).1
Moffitt (2001),Manski (1993,2000), Durlauf (2002), andDurlauf & Fafchamps
(2004) all depict the difficulties of estimating social capital models under the
presence of friendship,group, or neighborhood choice. Moffitt (2001) presents a
particularly lucid account. He points out that theestimation problems stem from
two distinct sources: simultaneous effects, in which peer or group effects are
overestimated because the outcomes of friends or group members simultaneously
^oreian (2001) provides a general treatment of the question of causality in the structure of
social networks. Although beyond the scope of this review, this general treatment would be
useful for anyone who wanted to tryexplicitly tomodel the process of friendship formation
with social network data.
This content downloaded from 205.213.172.3 on Mon, 28 Jul 2014 10:50:23 AM
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
CAUSAL EFFECTS OF SOCIAL CAPITAL 83
effecteach other, and correlated unobservables, inwhich friendship is related to
unobserved factors thatalso affect thedependent variable. Here, I present a simple
model thatclarifies thebasic issues.
Equation 1depicts a preference forfriendshiphomophily along twofixed char?
acteristics,Xi (observed by theresearcher) andw? (unobserved). Homophily prefer?
ences, i.e., the desire to associate with people who are similar to you, are
expressed
(forconvenience) by taking theabsolute value of thedifferencebetween potential
friends' characteristics,
Iijt
=
~?l I*/-Xj- ?2Wi
-
Wj+ Sijt, 1.
where e?jt is an error termand /?yfrepresents thepreference that individual ihas
to choose j as a friend at time t,with higher values indicatingmore desire to
be friends.2 In Equation 1, individuals who are similar in termsof x and w are
more likely tobecome friends.Equation 2 depicts theoutcome F as a functionof
individual characteristics and the average outcomes of one's friends, contacts, or
fellow groupmembers (see Blalock 1984, p. 363, fora discussion of thismodel),
Yit
=
ctY-it + a2x-it + o?3X? + a4w? + (pit, 2.
where both Y-n (the average outcome of fs friends/groupat time /)and x_zi (the
average x of f s friends/groupat time t) are possible measures of social capital.
Because w, is unobserved to the researcher,what he/she ends up estimating is
depicted inEquation 3:
Yit
=
aY-it + a2x-it + a3Xi + <pit. 3.
The difficulties ingettingaccurate resultsby estimatingEquation 3 can be depicted
as follows. One must first address the simultaneity or reflection problem (see
Manski 1993;Moffitt 2001, p. 54). If there is a social capital effectvia f_??, then
it is difficult to get an accurate estimate of a ibecause all theY? s are determined
simultaneously. As Manski puts it,"the problem is similar to thatof interpreting
the almost simultaneous movements of a person and his reflection in a mirror_
[D]oes themirror image cause theperson's movements or reflect them?" (p. 129).
With cross-sectional data, one must look for a variable to serve as an instrument
for Y, i.e., something that is correlated with theFs of your friends but not your
own F.With longitudinal data, it is possible to use the lagged outcomes of your
friends as an instrument for their current outcomes.3
The problem of correlated unobservables occurs when there is an unobserved
factor that is correlated with friendship (or group) choice and with theoutcome
variable. In Equation 3, the unobserved factorw? will bias the estimate of a?
2The negative signs in front of ?i and ?2 ensure that individuals who are similar
(i.e., smaller absolute differences in x and w) are more
likely to become friends.
3
Ifone uses a first difference model (see Halaby 2004), the first difference of the one-period
lagged outcome of your friends will be correlated, by definition, with the first difference of
the error term.
This content downloaded from 205.213.172.3 on Mon, 28 Jul 2014 10:50:23 AM
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
84 MOUW
(the coefficienton Y_it) ifw? is correlated with Yit (i.e., a4 ^ 0) and 1$ (?2 ^ 0).
Similarly, theestimate ofai (thecoefficientonx_tr)will be biased ifw? iscorrelated
with Xi and a4 ^ 0.
How much might thismatter? Table 1presents an example of how much bias
could result. In Table 1, I present results from simulated data for an imaginary
school of 5000 individuals.4The resultspresented inTable 1aremerely suggestive,
as they startfrom (arbitrary) known parameters and then generate the data to
be analyzed. In this simulation, x? and w? are jointly normally distributedwith a
correlation of0.25. InEquation 1,thevalues of ? and ?2 are set to 1.InEquation 2,
ot=0, i.e., no effect of ?_,-, and a2 =a3 =a4
= l.5 As discussed above, the
estimates of the coefficients for observed independent variables will be biased
because of a correlated unobservable, w?.The second column ofTable 1 shows the
truevalues of thecoefficients on the independent variables. Based on the results
of Equation 1, each simulated student selected 10 classmates as friendswith the
highest values of /#.The average values of Y and x for these 10 friends are used
to calculate 7_? and X-? for Equation 2.
Model 1ofTable 1 shows theordinary least square (OLS) resultsof estimating
Equation 3 for this data, where ?_? and %_,- are the average y and x values for each
student's 10 friends. Including F_? in themodel results ina statistically significant
effect,even though the truevalue for thecoefficienton f _, is zero. In addition, the
coefficienton x-? is downwardly biased. InModel 2, only theeffectsofx? and x^?
are estimated, and again the social capital effect is badly biased (1.702 versus 1.0
for the truevalue). The point here is not to argue thatthese results are definitive,
butmerely to suggest thateven in a very simplemodel, traditionalOLS estimates
of social capital effectsmay be verymisleading.
A REVIEWOF THE EMPIRICALEVIDENCEON CAUSAL
EFFECTS, BYMETHOD
Table 2 provides an overview of the studies reviewed in thispaper grouped by
the differentmethod used. I have grouped the papers bymethod rather than by
substantive topic toprovide a coherent critique of each methodological approach.
The methods discussed here are fixed effectsmodels, instrumentalvariables (IVs),
structural equations, randomly assigned roommates, and quasi-experimental de?
signs. In each of the sections thatfollow, Iprovide a briefdiscussion of thegeneral
methodological approach, followed by a detailed review of each of thedifferent
papers. None of these methodological approaches is new or
unique in their ap?
plication to social capital models. However, as depicted inTable 2, each of the
4The data was simulated using Stata. The computer files used in the simulation are available
on the author's website, http://www.tedmouw.org, for readers who wish to see the effect of
changing some of the parameters.
5In both equations, the error term is normally distributed with a variance of 3.
This content downloaded from 205.213.172.3 on Mon, 28 Jul 2014 10:50:23 AM
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
CAUSAL EFFECTS OF SOCIAL CAPITAL 85
TABLE 1 Monte-Carlo estimates of social capital with correlated unobservablesa
OLS
Model 1 Model 2
Fixed Effects
Model 3
Cross-Lagged
Regression
Model 4 Model 5
Variable
X;
True values'3
1.0
Social capital variables:
X-i
X-i,t-
Yu-i
Constant
Obs
R-squared
0
1.0
N.A.C
0
0
Yi Yt AY?
0.920 0.859
(0.096)** (0.098)**
0.485
(0.039)**
0.699 1.702 1.080
(0.193)** (0.178)** (0.171)*
0.031 0.058 -0.077
(0.045) (0.045) (0.060)
5000 5000 5000
0.29 0.27 0.01
Yi
0.774
(0.094)**
1.546
(0.168)**
0.120
(0.014)**
-0.026
(0.044)
5000
0.30
Yi
1.402
(0.097)*
0.262
(0.177)
0.127
(0.014)*
-0.028
(0.045)
5000
0.29
aStandarderrorsinparentheses significantat 5% level;double asterisk (**) indicatessignificantat 1% level; all thecomputer
filesforthisanalysis are available on theauthor'sweb page, http://www.tedmouw.org,ifreaderswish to repeat theanalysis
with differentparameters.
bSee Equation 2 in thetext.
CN.A.,not applicable, no directeffectinEquation 2.
differentapproaches makes certain assumptions, and the goal of this review is
to focus attention on the relative advantages and disadvantages ofmaking these
assumptions inestimating the trueeffectof social capital.
Fixed EffectsModels
If thebias in thesocial capitalmodel iscaused by fixed,unobserved characteristics,
such as w? inEquations 1 and 2, then a "firstdifference" or fixed effectsmodel
using longitudinal data can provide an unbiased estimate.Halaby (2004) provides
a clear discussion of thebenefits of fixed effectsmodels vis-?-vis other estimation
strategies such as random effectsand lagged dependent variables for longitudinal
data. A firstdifferencemodel estimates a regression of changes in thedependent
variable on changes in the independent variables for two timepoints, whereas a
fixed effectsmodel uses each variable's differencefrom itswithin-individual mean.
Conveniently, time-invariant variables, including unobserved ones, drop out of the
model. For example, Equation 2 becomes
Yit
-
%
=
ax
(?_,-,
-
fLf)
+ a2 (*-,-,
-
*,?) + #,-? 4.
This content downloaded from 205.213.172.3 on Mon, 28 Jul 2014 10:50:23 AM
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
86 MOUW
o+?
>>
&
S
?*
?s
c
-o
-
S ?.?
&su S
S SA*3
55 ? o
g ? u
^ o teM? +5 O?
C s 's
2 fi wi
5 S -S? ? 'S
5 2 fi
T3 +3 O
?i (Uj
J> Oh^
(D .a
e m IIft o
cd 3
?a
t*iC tzi
J3??3 <L>
> ta
^ ?s <4
?
^ a> ^
H O t?
'iJ<
3
t?O
?an"
?i
?a
Co-o
ine
?ffit/)
.a8
fr ?
t? o
*h 00
H? ON
cd
PQ
o
(S
O ^
o es
<NOw O
cd
^
3 f
Os o
CO
't? O Q
Isa
2| Js ?
?B e
cd Ui
2J
>
O
t?
Q a)
<D C
?3 Cd
O O
t? ^
t? O
-M C
<t?
13 ?2t? <u
?l
o ?
t?
O <D
te
? ?
t? T3
?S?
'S
-
Oh Cd
|?^g?s
1iO t/i
3 >
t?
ai .a
11 C .2
t? Sa --S M
pq
-" l~l
03 O ?-tt!- <L> <D
cd O
P t?
Oh t?
1*3?3C? -J-HcdT3
>,2
2*1
On
2 OO
w OS
^ go? t/3
fe
c^ ci
T3
c ^ 2>?rtrsi t?
Sa On =3
rafe?^ ^H t? a
'S P D to
t? ^
Sf?? fi<U -jj t?
cd t? <D
c3 ? O?
> 't? J2
?3 3 ?
g B s
s 5 ??p ?2 C?
J>1
This content downloaded from 205.213.172.3 on Mon, 28 Jul 2014 10:50:23 AM
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
CAUSAL EFFECTS OF SOCIAL CAPITAL 87
o
?5 'o
*?*
.^h
o ? o
?? ??3 s
S C rt ?
*
?13<D y c?
t? O <L>
G ce ^
i3 "?
3
o
c
a)
w>
o
X
S S
&
? <?
M
ctf <D
AS S
This content downloaded from 205.213.172.3 on Mon, 28 Jul 2014 10:50:23 AM
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
88 MOUW
where f _? and x-? axe mean values of Y-it and x-it. In Equation 4, changes in social
capital
over time, i.e., in Y-it and x-it, are caused by fluctuations in the composition
of one's friends thatare due to theerror term inEquation 1,which isuncorrelated
with thefixed, unobserved factor,w,-.A key advantage of fixed effects is thatthey
allow thefixed,unobserved factor tobe correlatedwith the independent variables,
whereas random effectsassume independence (Halaby 2004; Gordon et al. 2004,
p. 65). The principal assumption offixed effectsmodels is thatthefixed effectsdo
not change
over time.
Model 3 of Table 1 illustrates the accuracy of a fixed effects estimation of
Equation 4, provided these assumptions hold. The data were simulated in thesame
way as forModels 1 and 2, but for two timeperiods. Although xt and w, are fixed
over time, the error term inEquation 1 results in change in friendship rankings
over time, and hence in variation inY-it and x-it.Model 3 shows that thefixed
effectsmodel provides a good estimate of the effectof x-it, as the fixed effects
eliminate thefixed, unobserved effect,w?.
peer effects ON education The estimate of peer effects is problematic be?
cause a
positive correlation between students' test scores and grade point average
(GPA) could be caused by the sortingof students across schools that isbased on
factorsunobserved by theresearcher.Given thehigh degree of sortingby race and
class in schools in theUnited States, any cross-sectional estimate ofpeer effects is
likely tobe upwardly biased. One way to tackle theproblem of endogeneity ines?
timatingpeer effects is touse longitudinal data on individual students and schools
to studyhow changes in the composition of schools and classes affects changes
in individual students' test scores. The central problem is convincing the reader
that the unobserved factors are time invariant, i.e., that changes in the composi?
tionof peers are not simply a reflectionof thechanging school selectivity.Hoxby
(2000), Hanushek et al. (2003), Arcidiacono & Nicholson (2005), andAngrist &
Lang (2002) use fixed effectsmodels to control forfixed, unobserved factors at
the school and/or individual level.
Hoxby (2000) uses a rich data set from theTexas Schools Microdata Sample
thatallows her tofollow individual students inmore than3000 schools from 1990
1999. She argues thatidiosyncratic changes in thegender and race composition of
classrooms?differences by cohorts of students within the same school?reflect
random, exogenous variation in peer composition, as parents would be unlikely to
move in or out of a school district because of random, year-to-year perturbations in
thedemographic composition of a classroom. Provided thatthisassumption is true,
these small variations in class composition can be used to estimate peer effects.
Hoxby finds significantpeer effectsbased on these essentially random fluctuations
in classroom demographic composition. For example,
a random 10% increase in
theproportion of females in the class increases thirdgrade girls' reading scores
by 0.037 points and boys' reading scores by 0.047 points,with similar effects for
math scores. She notes thatthiseffectmay be due either to thefact thatgirls tend to
score higher on both testsat thisage inTexas (hence, an increase in thepercentage
female generates a peer effect by increasing the average test scores of students'
This content downloaded from 205.213.172.3 on Mon, 28 Jul 2014 10:50:23 AM
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
CAUSAL EFFECTS OF SOCIAL CAPITAL 89
classmates) or to theeffect thatchanging thegender composition of theclassroom
has on classroom behavior.
Also using the longitudinalTexas schools data,Hanushek et al. (2003) estimate
amodel of theeffectof average classmates' testscores on thechange in individual
test scores. They use individual, school, and school-by-grade fixed effects.Much
of the year-to-year fluctuation in theirdata is driven by annual mobility rates
of students across schools of about 20%. They use classmates' test scores from
two years before tomitigate what Manski (1993) calls the"reflection problem."6
Hanushek et al. (2003) find small but significantpeer effects in their full fixed
effectsmodels. A one-unit increase in theaverage math score of peers (standard
deviation 0.35) results ina 0.15-point increase inthechange intheaverage student's
math scores (standard deviation 0.63). It isworth noting, however, that in earlier
estimates of changes inmath scoreswithout the individual, school, and grade fixed
effects,Hanushek et al. finda negative effectof peers' scores on individual scores
(-0.07), which runs counter to thebasic intuitionabout peer effects (i.e., thatthey
should be upwardly biased because of sorting).7
The Texas microdata thatHoxby (2000) and Hanushek et al. (2003) use are
obviously quite remarkable and allow them to estimate models and obtain re?
sults that, if taken together,aremuch more convincing thanprevious estimates
of peer effects on academic achievement. Other researchwith differentdata has
found differentresults,however. Angrist & Lang (2002) analyze longitudinal data
on Boston's Metco program, which is a voluntary desegregation program that
buses (primarily low-income, black) inner-citystudents to suburban schools. They
find thatalthough the schools where theMetco students are placed experience
a decline in theiraverage test scores (which has made theprogram contentious
politically), thedecline is due entirely to a composition effect.They find no ev?
idence of negative peer effects:The change in the scores of non-Metco students
are not correlated with the number ofMetco students in the classroom. Arcidi
acono & Nicholson (2005) study peer effects on medical students and find no
evidence of an effectof average peerMCAT scores on fourthyear board scores
after they include school fixed effects; they argue that the correlation between
students' scores is due entirely to different levels of selectivity of the schools
themselves.
Overall, therecent evidence on peer effectsusing fixed effectsand longitudinal
data ismixed. In addition, although these fixed effectsmodels are a significant
improvement
over cross-sectional estimates of peer effects, one must always be
cautious of thepossibility thatchanges inunobserved factors such as the selectivity
or desirability of the school are driving theestimates of peer effects.
6Hanushek et al. (2003) use classmates test scores from two years before to avoid building
in a mechanical correlation with the dependent variable, which is the individual's change
in test scores over the past year.
7One possible explanation for this negative effect is, as Hanushek et al. (2003) note, a ceiling
effect on the standardized test scores. Nonetheless, it should make the reader cautious about
accepting the overall results.
This content downloaded from 205.213.172.3 on Mon, 28 Jul 2014 10:50:23 AM
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
90 MOUW
MIGRATION Social capital, in theformofmigrant networks,may provide infor?
mation and help thatfacilitatesmigration. Prima facie evidence on the importance
of social networks inmigration is given by thehigh rates of geographic and oc?
cupational concentration among different immigrantgroups. Hagan (1998), for
example, documents the role ofmigration networks in the growth of an immi?
grant community inHouston. For a general depiction of the role of networks in
migration, seeMassey (1993).
Palloni et al. (2001) testfor the role of social capital on theprobability ofmi?
gration by using sibling data from theMexican Migration Project. A high rate
of migration within a family or community may represent the effect of social
capital onmigration, or itmay be due to shared unmeasured characteristics. Pal?
loni et al. get around thisproblem by estimatingwhat amounts to a sibling fixed
effectsmodel, comparing theprobability ofmigration of individuals before and
afterone of theirsiblingsmigrates. Because theirdependent variable, firstmigra?
tion, is a discrete, nonrepeated event, a fixed effectsmodel similar toEquation
4 is not possible. Instead, thekey consideration of Palloni et al. is to allow for
a latentvariable topick up unobserved heterogeneity in thehazard ofmigration.
To see why this is important,consider the following example. Imagine a two
periodmodel ofmigration with two groups of sibling pairs,A andB, inwhich the
underlying probability ofmigration is higher for group A than forB (pa > Pb)
If thegroup is unobserved by the researcher, theneven in the absence of social
capital effects, theprobability ofmigrating inperiod twowill be higher ifyour
siblingmigrated than ifhe/she did not simply because relativelymore As than
Bs will have a siblingmigrate inperiod one (versus having no siblingsmigrate).
Palloni et al. (2001) note that theirmodel fits the data well with only two la?
tentstates, representinghigh and low unobserved migration propensities. Overall,
theyfind thathaving a siblingmigrate substantially increases thehazard of the
other siblingmigrating. The model is still sensitive to concerns that temporal
changes, such as a local recession or drought,will increase the joint probability
ofmigrating, but this is the same basic assumption thatall fixed effectsmodels
make.
peer effects ON delinquency Recognition of thedifficultyof differentiating
between peer effectsand social homophily incriminology extends back at least to
Glueck & Glueck (1950). In an analysis of thefriendsof 500 delinquent and non
delinquent boys, theyfound thatthemajority of thefriendsof 98.4% of delinquent
boys were delinquents, compared with only 7.4% of thefriends of nondelinquent
boys. However, because theboys in the studywere selected from largely the same
neighborhoods, and hence had similar opportunities toforge friendshipswith both
delinquents and nondelinquents, Glueck & Glueck argued that their results re?
flected the tendency that "birds of a featherflock together" and not of a causal
effectof peer influence (p. 164). Gottfredson & Hirschi (1987) provide a critique
of common methods of controlling for friendship selection in criminology, such
as thecross-lagged regressionmodel (p. 597).
This content downloaded from 205.213.172.3 on Mon, 28 Jul 2014 10:50:23 AM
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
CAUSAL EFFECTS OF SOCIAL CAPITAL 91
Gordon et al. (2004) use longitudinal data on gangmembership and delinquent
behavior and find strongeffectsof gang membership on self-reportedbehavior of
adolescents using fixed effectsmodels. Their research indicates thatthebehavior
of gang members cannot be entirely attributed to the self-selection of already
delinquent teens tojoin gangs, as criminal behavior increasedwhen therespondents
joined thegang and declined after they leftit.Again, thebenefit of thisapproach
is thatitnarrows theparameters of thedebate between peer effects and selection
effects.The effectsGordon et al. (2004) reportcould be caused by theidiosyncratic
changes in thedisposition tocommit delinquent acts if,say, some adolescents pass
through a period when they aremore likely to commit crimes and, as a result,
choose tojoin gangs, or, alternatively,by theeffectof gang membership on crime.
The onlyway togo furtherin resolving thequestion is to conduct an actual social
experiment or to suggest a plausible IV thatpicks up an exogenous change ingang
membership.
Rose et al. (1999) use data with peer and sibling reportsof smoking and find
an effectof peer smoking on respondents' smoking aftercontrolling for sibling
fixed effectsusing hierarchical linearmodeling (HLM). Of course, thisdoes not
rule out thepossibility thatdifferences inpeer smoking levels among siblings are
caused by differentfriendshippreferences among the siblings, but it is useful in
indicating thattheobserved peer correlation in smoking isnot solely attributable
tofixed tendencies to smoke based on shared genetic and/orhome environment
among siblings.Finally, Bayer et al. (2003) use longitudinal data on 8000 juveniles
serving time indifferentcorrectional institutionsinFlorida to study therole ofpeer
effectson recidivism.Using fixed effectsfor thecorrectional institutiontocontrol
for selectivity of assignment todifferentfacilities, theyfind that theprobability
of recidivism for specific crimes varies according to the criminal histories of the
peers who are
serving in the same institution at the same time.
labor market SOCIAL CAPITAL Mouw (2003) provides an overview and critique
of the literatureon theeffectof social capital in the labormarket. He proposes an
indirecttestofwhether a proposed social capital variable is trulycausal orwhether
itis simplypicking up a spurious effectowing to social homophily. He shows that,
ifall else is equal, workers with more social capital should be more likely touse
contacts tofindwork. His results suggest thatoft-usedmeasures of labormarket
social capital, such as theaverage education or job prestige of your contacts, have
a
spurious, rather than causal, effect on wages. This does not
necessarily mean that
social capital does notmatter, butmerely thatwe need tofindbettermeasures of
it.
Fixed effectsmodels have also been used toassess therole of social networks in
the labormarket.Mouw (2002) uses longitudinal data to assess racial differences
in theeffectofusing job contacts tofindwork. He finds thatwhereas black workers
who used contacts have lower wages in cross-sectional models, this is not the case
when one follows workers over time;workers who used contacts inone period did
not do any betterwhen theydid not use contacts tofindwork. This suggests that
This content downloaded from 205.213.172.3 on Mon, 28 Jul 2014 10:50:23 AM
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
92 MOUW
it is not theuse of contacts per se but ratherpoorer job opportunities in general
(partofwhich could be due todifferences in social capital) thatcontributed to the
racialwage gap. Yakubovich (2005) uses a fixed effectsapproach inan innovative
way to test the "strengthofweak ties" hypothesis. He collected data onmultiple
potential contacts foreach worker and found that,net of individual fixed effects,
weak tieswere more likely than strong ties tohave led to a job. Although neither
of thesepapers directly tests theeffectof social capital on labormarket outcomes
overall, they illustratethepotential benefits of a fixed effectsapproach.
Instrumental Variables and Structural Equations
One solution to theproblem of correlated unobservables depicted inEquations
1-3 is tofind an IV thatis correlatedwith the independent variable of interestbut
notwith theunobserved factor. InEquation 2, thiswould entail finding a variable
Zi thatwas correlatedwith x? but notwith theunobserved factor,w,. The problem
with this approach is thatbecause w? is unobserved, there is no way to prove
thata potential Zi variable is actually a good instrument.Instead, the researcher
must relyon theoretical justifications. Inmany instances, researchers have chosen
instrumentson weak theoretical grounds. As Moffitt (2001) notes, "thus far the
instrumentschosen have generally been ad hoc innature and notbased on a strong,
or at least explicitly formulated theory" (p. 70). Ifan instrumentispoorly chosen
such that it is still correlated with the error term, then the estimates may be as
biased, ifnotmore so, as models thatdo not try to account for selectivity. In
addition, the resultsmay depend on the researcher's arbitrary choice among a
number of potential instruments,with little theoretical difference justifying the
choice.
Evans et al. (1992) study the effectof peer influences on teenage pregnancy
using National Longitudinal Survey ofYouth (NLS Y) data, using thepercentage
of students in therespondent's school who are classified as disadvantaged as their
peer group measure. Preliminarymodels indicate that thepeer groupmeasure is
significantly associated with the respondent's probability of teenage pregnancy,
but Evans et al. provide a good discussion of why thepeer effectmay be over?
estimated owing to correlated unobservables, and theyargue thatan IV approach
is needed. They note that theyneed a set of IVs that are correlated with peer
group characteristics and are uncorrelated with the error term on teen pregnancy.
The instruments that they choose are the metropolitan area
unemployment rate,
median family income, poverty rate, and thepercentage of adults with a college
degree. Although theynote thatthesevariables are not strongpredictors of teenage
pregnancy, this does not mean that they are not correlated with the error term. This
cannot be proven; itcan only be argued theoretically.The IV results show thatthe
peer group effect disappears. However, the reader is left to wonder whether these
variables really are
good indicators of exogenous changes in peer group character?
istics and what sortof biases may resultby using themas instruments.As Moffitt
(2001) suggests, they seem ad hoc. The benefit of theEvans et al. (1992) paper
This content downloaded from 205.213.172.3 on Mon, 28 Jul 2014 10:50:23 AM
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
CAUSAL EFFECTS OF SOCIAL CAPITAL 93
is that it shows therecan be a wide divergence between OLS and IV estimates,
even if the IV results are based on assumptions thatmay be as problematic as the
original OLS results.
Structural equation models (SEMs) represent an elaboration of thebasic IV
approach. SEMs are useful in dealing with problems ofmeasurement error and
latentvariables with multiple indicators, both ofwhich may apply, obviously, in
social capital research. They cannot, however, resolve thedebate between social
capital and social homophily without making assumptions about theunderlying
causal structure, assumptions that are
ultimately untestable and subject to second
guessing. In this sense, theymerely transformthe nature of the debate into an
argument over the validity of instruments, causal diagrams,
or
assumptions about
thedistributionof theerror term. I believe a key consideration is thattheassump?
tions thataremade inorder to identifythemodel may seem innocuous to a naive
reader but could turnout to have profound empirical consequences. As argued
above, I believe that it is critically important that the assumptions used to iden?
tifythemodel, i.e., the assumptions behind theuse of the IV, be made explicit
to the reader.McDonald (1997) shows thateven with a simple data set,different,
seemingly arbitraryassumptions about thepath diagram can lead to substantively
different parameter estimates.
With longitudinal data, a frequent approach to the endogeneity problem has
been to use "cross-lagged" SEMs to tryto estimate reciprocal effects between
peer selection and individual behavior. In thesemodels, measures of peer and
individual behavior are regressed on laggedmeasures of both variables. Building
on our previous discussion of Equations 1-4, a cross-lagged model would look
like this:
x-itt
=
bYitt- + ?>2*-*,r-i + b3Xi +et, 5.
Yi,t
=
c Yitt-i + c2x-i,t + c&i + uu6.
where x-it is theaverage value of thex?of individual fs friendsat time t(althoughx
does not change, each individual's friendsmay change), and Ytis therespondent's
outcome at time t.The lagged value of Y inEquation 6 is intended to control for
unmeasured factors that affect Y, which in our case would be the unobserved
variable wt fromEquation 2. However, Halaby (2004, pp. 52-62)8 shows thata
regression on Equation 6 is not a general solution to theproblem of unobserved
fixed effects (in contrast tofixed effectsmodels), nor does it solve theproblem of
nonstationary, unobserved effects.9 In the presence of a fixed effect, such as wt, the
8Note that page numbers for Halaby (2004) refer to a longer, online version of the
review, which may be viewed at
http://www.ssc.wisc.edu/soc/faculty/pages/Ann_Revl3
total_web.pdf.
9In the case of true state dependence, taking firstdifferences of all the variables inEquation 6
will eliminate the fixed effects, but bias is still introduced because the change in the error
term is correlated with the change in the lagged dependent variable.
This content downloaded from 205.213.172.3 on Mon, 28 Jul 2014 10:50:23 AM
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
94 MOUW
lagged dependent variablewill be, by definition,correlatedwith thecomposite error
term (a4Wi+ (pitfromEquation 2). As Halaby (2004) notes, "serially correlated
errors in amodel with a lagged dependent variable render least squares estimates
biased and inconsistent" (p. 57). Rogosa (1980) is critical of the claim of cross
lagged models tomeasure reciprocal causation, showing thateven in a simple
two-variable case without measurement error, the cross-lagged model may produce
inconsistent results.He argues thatcross-lagged SEMs "should be set aside as a
dead end" (p. 257).
Models 4 and 5 ofTable 1 illustratewhat can gowrong with a lagged dependent
variable. Model 4 estimates Equation 6 for the simulated data thatwere used to
estimate thefixed effectsmodel inModel 3,whereas Model 5 estimates amodified
formofEquation 6 where thecurrentvalue of X-it isused rather than the lagged
value. The estimate of the true social capital effectx-u is badly biased in both
models. Models 4 and 5 show thateven in a well-behaved, simulated example, a
lagged dependent variable is not a solution for theproblem of fixed unobserved
effects.
Matsueda & Anderson (1998) and Schulenberg et al. (1999) use cross-lagged
models to estimate peer influenceson delinquent behavior. Although both papers
provide good discussions of the central issue of selection versus influence, in?
spection of theproposed causal path diagrams reveals thateach ismaking strong
assumptions regarding thenonexistence ofpaths between certainvariables inorder
to identifythemodel. As with theEvans et al. (1992) paper, thesepapers are useful
because they illustrate the range of estimates thatcan be found given semiplau?
sible assumptions about themodeling strategy.Aseltine (1995) estimates a SEM
of reciprocal effectsbetween peer and respondent delinquency andmarijuana use
with three-wave panel data, using lagged values as IVs of the contemporaneous
measures. His paper is insightfulbecause itgives a detailed account of theassump?
tions thatare necessary to estimate themodel, in particular the assumption that
there is no direct effectbetween lagged peer behavior and respondent behavior
(i.e., itall operates via currentpeer behavior). Given Halaby's (2004) argument
that lagged variables are not an adequate solution for theproblem of unobserved
fixed effects,Aseltine's approach may not sufficeto takecare of thepossibility that
the relationship between peer and respondent behavior is the result of correlated
unobservables, i.e., the w? in Equation 2. In sum, given that one has to accept the
assumption thatthepath diagram is specified correctly inorder to trusttheresults
(i.e., the results of a SEM do not prove that themodel is correct), none of these
papers is likely to convince skeptics thattheyhave uncovered the"true" effectof
peer influence unless they
can make a
strong case that the assumptions they make
are tenable.
"Exogenous" Instrumental Variables
The distinction between this section and theprevious one is amatter of degree.
In some cases, the use of a
particular IV may be a reasonable solution to the
This content downloaded from 205.213.172.3 on Mon, 28 Jul 2014 10:50:23 AM
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
CAUSAL EFFECTS OF SOCIAL CAPITAL 95
endogeneity problem. In this section I discuss twopapers inwhich thisapproach
seems credible.
Munshi (2003) studies the effect of network size on employment among
Mexican immigrantsusing rainfall patterns in origin communities as an instru?
ment for network size at the destination. Munshi uses data from theMexican
Migration Project (MMP) to estimate fixed effectsmodels of unemployment and
occupational choice. Although theMMP is a repeated cross-sectional surveycon?
ducted inMexico, ithas lifehistorydata on respondents' location and employment
status. From these data, Munshi constructs person-year longitudinal data indicat?
ingwhether the respondent is living inMexico or theUnited States and whether
therespondentworked more thanone month during theyear (which serves as the
measure of employment).
For the agricultural communities in theMMP data,Munshi shows that lower
levels of rainfallare empirically associated with higher numbers ofmigrants in the
United States one to threeyears later. Intuitively, low rainfallwould reasonably
decrease agricultural wages and make migration to theUnited States relatively
more attractive.As thesemigrants establish themselves in theUnited States, they
can serve as sources ofjob informationand help forsubsequentmigrantswho arrive
from the same origin community.Munshi uses individual fixed effectsmodels to
account forthepossibility thatrainfallaffectsthe selectivityofmigration.Migrants
who anticipate poor employment prospects in theUnited Statesmightmigrate only
in theevent of a drought in theirorigin community, therebydownwardly biasing
models thatdo not include individual fixed effects. Inmodels inwhich rainfall is
used as an IV for thenumber of established migrants from theorigin community
in theUnited States,Munshi finds thatpredicted network size has a substantial
effecton theemployment probability of immigrantworkers.
The only problemwithMunshi's (2003) paper is thatthecalculated employment
rates for themigrants in theUnited States are very high, about 95%-96%. This
may be partly due to the fact that,because of data constraints,Munshi counts as
employed anyone who worked at least one month in theUnited States during the
calendar year.As Munshi notes, thehigh employment rates and theuse of fixed
effectsmodels mean thathis results are being driven by the small percentage of
migrants who were unemployed duringone year in theUnited States and employed
in another year (generating variation in the dependent variable). Given that the
immigrants in thedata have come to theUnited States towork andmany will have
paid substantial sums ofmoney to cross theborder, it is hard tobelieve thatany
of themwould spend a fullyear in theUnited States without working at least one
month or thatmany would returnvoluntarily without having earned enough to
recoup theexpenses of crossing theborder.Hence, it ispossible thatthe5% who
are unemployed were deported before theycould work or are special cases in some
otherway. In supplementalmodels, Munshi uses occupation in themost recent trip
to theUnited States as a dependent variable and shows thatincreasing thenetwork
size increases theprobability of securingnonagricultural employment, again using
rainfall as the instrumentfor the size of themigrant network.
This content downloaded from 205.213.172.3 on Mon, 28 Jul 2014 10:50:23 AM
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
96 MOUW
Although using the same approach inother contextsmay be difficult,Munshi's
paper is a splendid example ofhow progress can bemade in social capital research
by thecreative use of existing data. The unique twist to thispaper is thatit is able
toexploit thegeographic distance between theorigin and destination communities
to use weather as an IV
Bayer et al. (2004) use census data on residential and job location fromBoston
tostudy theeffectof referralnetworks on employment.They find thatworkers from
differenthouseholds who live in the same census block (roughly theequivalent toa
cityblock) are 50% more likely towork in the same location thanareworkers who
live in the same block group but differentblocks. Because thereare, on average,
tencensus blocks ineach block group in theirdata, theyargue thatthisresult isdue
to the sharing of job informationamong people who live in the same geographic
area. They use block-group fixed effects toaccount for thepossibility thatworkers
select theirneighborhood based on unobserved factors that are also correlated
with where theywork. The underlying assumption is thatthe selectivityoperates
at theblock-group level but not at theblock level within block groups. Another
possible interpretationof theirresults is that theyare due to reverse causality?
the tendency of coworkers to share house or apartment information.They tryto
account for thispossibility by restrictingsomemodels toworkers who have lived
in theneighborhood forat least 2 years andwho worked less than40 weeks during
theprevious year as a proxy for a spell of unemployment preceding a new job.
Although census data are not ideal forpicking apart temporal order, the results
seem to support their basic argument.
Randomly Assigned Roommates
Recently, an important literaturehas developed thatuses randomly assigned col?
lege roommates as a natural experiment to estimate the effectof social capital.
Although many colleges assign roommates based on answers to a listof prefer?
ences (i.e., smoking/nonsmoking), provided the researcher knows theanswers to
these questions, the assignment is essentially random on unobserved factors.
Sacerdote (2001), Zimmerman (2003), McEwan & Soderberg (2005), and
Stinebrickner & Stinebrickner (2004) (hereafter S&S) estimate models of the
effectof (randomly assigned) roommate's precollege academic achievement on
respondent's college GPA. The strikingresult is thatthere isno evidence of a lin?
ear effectof roommate quality on college achievement. Although Sacerdote (2001)
has been cited as evidence of a positive finding of peer effectsbecause he finds
a
positive correlation among freshman GPAs, he notes that this cannot be treated
as evidence of a causal peer effect (p. 694) because of the reflectionproblem and
because itmight indicatemutually experienced events. A better estimate is the
relationship between roommate high school academic achievement and freshman
GPA (because high school achievement is obtained prior to the common expe?
rience as roommates). The coefficient of roommates' high school test scores on
freshmanGPA is found tobe -.001 (s.e. 0.001) (Sacerdote 2001, model 1, table 3).
This content downloaded from 205.213.172.3 on Mon, 28 Jul 2014 10:50:23 AM
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
CAUSAL EFFECTS OF SOCIAL CAPITAL 97
Zimmerman (2003), S&S, andMcEwan & Soderberg (2005) all find similar re?
sults.10As S&S discuss, there is slight evidence of a nonlinear effect in both
Sacerdote (2001) andZimmerman (2003), but theresults are not consistent across
thedifferentarticles.11
What should we make of these findings? Randomly assigned roommates are,
arguably, the cleanest estimates we will get of social capital effectsbecause they
avoid thequestion of friendship choice thatcomplicates the restof the literature.
It could be, however, that the effect is simply too small to show up; hence, the
null findingswould not indicate thatsocial capital does notmatter, butmerely that
thesemodels are not picking itup. In addition, S&S note thattheamount of time
you spend with your roommate depends on how well you get along, and hence
potential negative effectsofbad studyhabits and/orpoor academic preparation are
mitigated by simply avoiding your roommate.12 S&S suggest thatmore attention
should be paid to the concrete ways inwhich roommate effectsmight operate,
arguing that study habits rather than achievement test scores are where a causal
effectmight lie. In their study of roommates at Berea College, S&S find that
although achievement scores have no effect, there is evidence of a positive effect
of roommates' high schoolGPA on freshmanGPA forfemales (butnot formales),
and theyclaim thatthis represents thebenefit thatstudentswith poor study skills
may obtain by observing roommates with good study skills.
The use of roommate data revolutionizes theestimation of social capital effects
with quasi-experimental data. Clearly, it is a special situationbecause therandom
assignment of roommates isundertaken by colleges forother reasons; nonetheless,
this is precisely thekind of creative use of data that lends hope to the idea of
estimating causal effects of social capital. At themoment, the lack of a clear
finding of peer effects in these studies should give the researcher pause even if
he/she is notworking in the social capital and education literature.
Marmarosa & Sacerdote (2002) apply the randomly assigned roommate tech?
nique to labormarket outcomes. Using data on randomly assigned freshmanyear
roommates atDartmouth and informationon respondents' firstjob after college,
theyfindno correlation between roommates in theprobability of receiving a high
paying job. There is,however, an effectof freshmanyear hallmates' average salary
10The corresponding estimates of the linear effect of high school achievement index on
freshman grades are .007 (s.e. .009) for SAT scores inMcEwan & Soderberg (2005), .007
(s.e. .006) using SAT scores in Zimmerman (2003), and .0009 (for males, s.e. .0052) to
.0015 (for females, s.e. .0044) using ACT scores in S&S.
11
In a related approach, Kang (2005) studies the peer effects on education using the random
assignment of students to classrooms within middle schools in Korea. Kang finds that a
1 standard deviation inpeer math scores is associated with a 0.27 standard deviation increase
in students' math scores, controlling for school fixed effects.
12
Of course, once one accepts the fact that the amount of time roommates spend together,
and consequently the effect they have on each other, depends on how well they get along,
then this introduces some of the problem of endogeneity of friendship choice back into the
model.
This content downloaded from 205.213.172.3 on Mon, 28 Jul 2014 10:50:23 AM
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
98 MOUW
on the respondent's salary (t-statistic2.27). They conclude thatthis isdue topeer
effects on career choice and help in obtaining jobs. Although this interpretation
seems plausible, it is hard to reconcile thepositive finding on hallmates with the
null results for roommates.
Kremer & Levy (2003) and Duncan et al. (2005) study theeffectof randomly
assigned roommates on grades and alcohol and drug use during college. Kremer
& Levy (2003) find thatamong studentswho reporteddrinking frequently inhigh
school, random assignment of a roommatewho also reporteddrinking frequently
reduced the student'sGPA by a fullpoint.Duncan et al. (2005) find that,among
male (butnot female) college students,iftwohigh school binge drinkers are paired
together,theyaremore likely tobinge drink in college than ifa binge drinker is
paired to a nonbinge drinker.
Quasi-Experimental Evidence
Recent evidence from theMoving toOpportunity (MTO) program can be used
to estimate the role thatneighborhood effectsplay on outcomes such as work,
crime, and education. The MTO program is a large-scale housing mobility exper?
iment conducted infive cities. Interested families were randomly assigned to an
experimental or control group. Experimental group families were given housing
vouchers to live in a low-poverty neighborhood, whereas control group families
did not receive the vouchers (Kling et al. 2005). Because both the experimental
and control groups consist of familieswho wanted to receive housing vouchers, a
comparison of theresults forfamilieswho did receive vouchers (the experimental
group) and thosewho did not (thecontrol group) arguably overcomes much of the
problem of correlated unobservables thatplagues the analysis of neighborhood
effects. Sanbonmatsu et al. (2006) study the effect of receivingMTO housing
vouchers on children's academic achievement forover 5000 children 4-7 years
afterthe startof theexperiment.They find thatalthough receiving aMTO voucher
resulted infamiliesmoving toneighborhoods with significantlylowerpoverty rates
(33% versus 45.6% for thecontrol group), therewas no difference in thechildren's
achievement test scores or measures of school or behavioral problems for any age
group (p. 23). These results appear to reverse thefindings of the three-yearfol?
low up of theBaltimore MTO program, which found evidence of positive results
(Ludwig et al. 2005). Sanbonmatsu et al. (2006) argue that theirnull results are
"particularly surprising" for the youngest children who spent a
larger proportion of
theirlives living in thenew neighborhood environment.They suggest thatone ex?
planation for thefindings is thattheeffecton school quality of receiving vouchers,
though significant,was more modest than theeffecton neighborhood poverty rates
(the average percentile rank of the school on state exams was 4.1 points higher
for the experimental group). At the same time, they conclude that the evidence
from nonexperimental data is probably overestimated because of selection effects
and thatthe true impact ofmoving families frompoor neighborhoods is probably
small. The null results forchildren's outcomes are similar to themagnitude of the
This content downloaded from 205.213.172.3 on Mon, 28 Jul 2014 10:50:23 AM
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
CAUSAL EFFECTS OF SOCIAL CAPITAL 99
findings on employment and earnings foradults (Kling et al. 2005, Ludwig et al.
2005). These MTO findings are corroborated by similar housing voucher results
fromChicago (Jacob 2004).
The resultsfromtheMTO program do notdirectlyaddress therole of social cap?
italon theseoutcomes, as theunderlyingmechanism behind neighborhood effects
is not clearly theorized ormeasured. Indeed, simplymoving to a new neighbor?
hood with a lower poverty ratewill not increase your social capital unless it is
accompanied by actual social integration into thenetworks of theneighborhood.
Pettit& McLanahan (2003), forexample, study theeffectof residentialmobility
on twomeasures of social capital in theMTO program inLos Angeles, the fre?
quency thatparents talk to theparents of theirchildren's friendsand thenumber of
extracurricularactivities thechild participated in.They find thata smaller percent?
age of theexperimental group had talked to friends' parents over thepastmonth
compared with the control group (72.7% versus 76.6%) but that thepercentage
participating inactivitieswas thesame. So, a reasonable interpretationof theMTO
results is thata network-based measure of social capital (talking to friends' par?
ents) indicates littlechange for those familieswho moved, therebyindicating that
theMTO program isnot a direct testof therole of social capital on theseoutcomes.
Nonetheless, because neighborhood characteristics such as the poverty rate are of?
tenused as proxies forneighborhood social capital, theMTO results suggest that
we should exercise caution in interpretingtheestimated effectof thesemeasures
with nonexperimental data. The randomized housing studies provide an important
example of both thedifficultyand potential benefits of quasi-experimental data.
CONCLUSION
If individuals choose friendswho are similar to them, thenone may reasonably
suspect thattheeffectsofmany social capital variables are overestimated because
of unobserved, individual-level factors thatare correlated with friendship choice
and theoutcome variable of interest.This is not an argument that social capital
does notmatter, butmerely a suspicion thatmany existing empirical estimates
of theeffectof social capital are notmuch of an improvement over our intuition
or anecdotal conviction that itdoes matter. Overall, the evidence reviewed here
suggests thatwhen theproblem of endogenous friendship choice is taken intoac?
count by amethod thatattempts todeal with itexplicitly, theresultingestimates of
social capital effects are modest in size, ranging from essentially
zero for the ma?
jorityof theestimates using randomly assigned roommates (see rowD ofTable 2)
to the small, but significant,coefficients reported infixed effectsmodels of peer
effects in education or juvenile delinquency (rowA of Table 2). Again, as de?
picted in column 2 of Table 2, each of thedifferentmethodological approaches
involves making certain assumptions, and the reader should be cautious about
interpretingthe results ofmodels inwhich the assumptions are strong and/or
not clearly explained. The evidence reviewed here, combined with the theoretical
This content downloaded from 205.213.172.3 on Mon, 28 Jul 2014 10:50:23 AM
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
100 MOUW
argumentbehind why friendshipchoice may bias estimates of network social capi?
tal, should lead social capital researchers to take theproblem of causality seriously.
Munshi (2003) provides thebest example of a credible IV because, as discussed
above, rainfall patterns inMexico provide
a
reasonably exogenous instrument for
the size ofmigrant networks in theUnited States several years later,as theyaf?
fect local opportunities but do not reflectchanges in opportunities in theUnited
States.
However, theprimary purpose of this review is to show that theproblem of
nonrandom friendship choice, although posing serious problems for empirical
research, is not insoluble. The literaturereviewed in thispaper addresses theen
dogeneity of social capital directly and presents innovative attempts to improve
the estimation of social capital effects.Although the papers reviewed here are
dispersed across several disciplines and substantive topics, theircreativemethod?
ological approaches may provide a useful template forfutureresearchers toarrive
at amore definitive conclusion regarding theeffectof social capital on individual
outcomes.
The Annual Review of Sociology isonline at http://soc.annuaIreviews.org
LITERATURECITED
Angrist JD, Lang K. 2002. How important
are classroom peer effects? Evidence from
Boston's Metco Program. NBER Work.
Pap. 9263, Nati. Bur. Econ. Res. http://
www.nber.org/papers/w9263
Arcidiacono P, Nicholson S. 2005. Peer effects
inmedical school. J. Public Econ. 89:327-50
Aseltine RH. 1995. A reconsideration of
parental and peer influences on adolescent
deviance. J.Health Soc. Behav. 36 2:103-21
Bayer P, Pintoff R, Pozen DE. 2003. Build?
ing criminal capital behind bars: social
learning injuvenile corrections. Work. Pap.
864, Econ. Growth Cent., Yale Univ. http://
ideas.
repec.org/p/egc/wpaper/864.html
Bayer P, Ross SL, Topa G. 2004. Place of work
and place of residence: informal hiring
networks and labor market outcomes. Work.
Pap. 2004-07, Dep. Econ., Univ. Conn.
http:/Adeas.repec.org/p/uct/uconnp/2004-07.
html
Blalock. 1984. Contextual effects models: theo?
retical and
methodological issues. Annu. Rev.
Sociol. 10:353-72
Card D. 1999. The causal effect of education on
earnings. InHandbook of Labor Economics,
Vol. 3, ed. O Ashenfelter, D Card, pp. 1801
63. Amsterdam: Elsevier
Card D. 2001. Estimating the return to school?
ing: progress on some persistent econo?
metric problems. Econometrica 69(5): 1127
60
Cohen JM. 1977. Sources of peer group homo?
geneity. Sociol. Educ. 50(4):227-^l
Doreian P. 2001. Causality in social network
analysis. Sociol. Methods Res. 30(1):81?114
Duncan G, Boisjoly J,Kremer M, Levy DM,
Eccles J. 2005. Peer effects in drug use and
sex among college students. /. Abnorm. Child
Psychol. 33:375-85
Duncan OD, Haller AO, Portes A. 1968. Peer
influences on aspirations: a reinterpretation.
Am. J. Sociol. 74:119-37
Durlauf SN. 2002. On the empirics of so?
cial capital. Econ. J. Royal Econ. Soc.
112(483):459-79
Durlauf SN, Fafchamps M. 2004. Social
capital. NBER Work. Pap. 10485, Nati.
Bur. Econ. Res.
http://www.nber.org/papers/
w10485
This content downloaded from 205.213.172.3 on Mon, 28 Jul 2014 10:50:23 AM
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
CAUSAL EFFECTS OF SOCIAL CAPITAL 101
Evans WN, Oates WE, Schwab RM. 1992.
Measuring peer effects: a study of teenage
behavior. J. Polit. Econ. 100:966-91
Fischer C. 2005. Bowling alone: what's the
score? Soc. Networks 27:155-67
Friedkin NE. 1990. Social networks in struc?
tural equation models. Soc. Psychol. Q.
53:316-28
Fukuyama F. 1999. The Great Disruption.
New York: Simon & Schuster
Glueck S, Glueck E. 1950. Unraveling Juve?
nile Delinquency. Cambridge, MA: Harvard
Univ. Press
Gordon RA, Lahey BB, Kawai E, Loeber R,
Stouthamer-Loeber M, Farrington DP. 2004.
Antisocial behavior and youth gang mem?
bership: selection and socialization. Crimi?
nology42(l):55-89
Gottfredson MR, Hirschi T. 1987. The method?
ological adequacy of longitudinal research in
crime and delinquency. Criminology 25:581?
614
Hagan J. 1998. Social networks, gender and im?
migrant settlement: resource and constraint.
Am. Sociol. Rev. 63(l):55-67
Halaby C. 2004. Panel models in sociological
research: theory into practice. Annu. Rev. So?
ciol. 30:507^4
Hanushek E, Kain JF, Markman JM, Rivkin
SG. 2003. Does peer ability affect stu?
dent achievement? J. Appl. Econometr.
18(5):527-44
Hoxby CM. 2000. Peer effects in the classroom:
learning from gender and race variation.
NBER Work. Pap. 7867, Nati. Bur. Econ.
Res. http://papers.nber.org/papers/w7867
Jacob BA. 2004. Public housing, housing
vouchers, and student achievement: evidence
from public housing demolitions inChicago.
Am. Econ. Rev. 94(l):233-58
Kadushin C. 2004. Too much investment
in social capital? Soc. Networks 26:75
90
Kandel DB. 1978. Homophily, selection and so?
cialization in adolescent friendships. Am. J.
Sociol. 84:427-36
Kang C. 2005. Classroom peer effects and aca?
demic achievement: quasi-randomization ev
idence from South Korea. Work. Pap., Dep.
Econ., Nati. Univ. Singapore
Kling JR, Liebman JB, Katz LF. 2005. Ex?
perimental analysis of neighborhood effects.
NBER Work. Pap. 11577, Nati. Bur. Econ.
Res. http://www.nber.org/papers/wl 1577
Kremer M, Levy DM. 2003. Peer effects and
alcohol use among college students. NBER
Work. Pap. 9876, Nati. Bur. Econ. Res.
http://www.nber.org/papers/w9876
Ludwig J,Duncan G, Pinkston JC. 2005. Hous?
ing mobility programs and economic self
sufficiency: evidence from a randomized ex?
periment. J. Public Econ. 89(1): 131-56
Manski C. 1993. Identification of endogenous
social effects: the reflection problem. Rev.
Econ. Stud. 60:531-42
Manski C. 2000. Economic analysis of social
interactions. J. Econ. Perspect. 14:114-36
Marmarosa D, Sacerdote B. 2002. Peer and so?
cial networks in job search. Eur. Econ. Rev.
46:870-79
Massey D. 1993. Theories of international mi?
gration. Popul. Dev. Rev. 19(3):431-66
Matsueda RL, Anderson K. 1998. The dynam?
ics of delinquent peers and delinquent behav?
ior. Criminology 36:269-308
McDonald R. 1997. Haldane's lungs: a case
study in path analysis. Multivar. Behav. Res.
32(l):l-38
McEwan PJ, Soderberg KA. 2005. Room?
mate effects on grades: evidence from first
year housing assignments. Work. Pap., Dep.
Econ., Wellesley Coll.
McPherson M, Smith-Lovin L, Cook JM. 2001.
Birds of a feather: homophily in social net?
works. Annu. Rev. Sociol. 27:415^4
Moffitt R. 2001. Policy interventions, low-level
equilibria and social interactions. In Social
Dynamics, ed. S Durlauf, P Young, pp. 45
82. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press
Mouw T. 2002. Racial differences in the ef?
fects of job contacts: conflicting evidence
from cross-sectional and longitudinal data.
Soc. Sei. Res. 31 (4):511-38
Mouw T. 2003. Social capital and finding a job:
do contacts matter? Am. Sociol. Rev. 68:868
98
This content downloaded from 205.213.172.3 on Mon, 28 Jul 2014 10:50:23 AM
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
102 MOUW
Munshi K. 2003. The identification of network
effects: Mexican migrants in the U.S. labor
market. Q. J. Econ. 118:549-97
Palloni A, Massey D, Ceballos M, Espinosa K,
Spittel M, 2001. Social capital and interna?
tional migration: a test using information on
family networks. Am. J. Sociol. 106:1262
98
Pettit B, McLanahan S. 2003. Residential mo?
bility and children's social capital: evidence
from an experiment. Soc. Sei. Q. 84(3):632
49
Portes A. 1998. Social capital: its origins and
applications inmodern sociology. Annu. Rev.
Sociol. 24:1-24
Rogosa DR. 1980. A critique of cross-lagged
correlation. Psychol. Bull. 88:245-258
Rose JS, Chassin L, Presson CC, Sherman
SJ. 1999. Peer influences on adolescent
cigarette smoking: a prospective sibling anal?
ysis. Merrill-Palmer Q. 45:62-79
Sacerdote B. 2001. Peer effects with random
assignment: results with Dartmouth room?
mates. Q. J. Econ. 116(2):681-704
Sanbonmatsu L, Kling JR,Duncan GJ, Brooks
Gunn J. 2006. Neighborhoods and aca?
demic achievement: results from theMov?
ing to Opportunity experiment. NBER
Work. Pap. 11909, Nati. Bur. Econ. Res.
http://papers.nber.0rg/papers/w 11909
Schulenberg J,Maggs JL, Dielman TE, Leech
SL, Kloska DD, et al. 1999. On peer influ?
ences to get drunk: a panel study of young
adolescents. Merrill-Palmer Q. 45:108-142
Sobel ME. 1995. Causal inference in the social
and behavioral sciences. InHandbook of Sta?
tistical Modeling for the Social and Behav?
ioral Sciences, ed. G Arminger, CC Clogg,
ME Sobel, pp. 1-38. New York: Plenum
Stinebrickner T, Stinebrickner R. 2004. What
can be learned about peer effects using col?
lege roommates? Evidence from new sur?
vey data and students from disadvantaged
backgrounds. Work. Pap., Dep. Econ., Univ.
Western Ontario
Winship C, Sobel M. 2004. Causal inference
in sociological studies. InHandbook ofData
Analysis, ed. M Hardy, A Bryman, pp. 481
503. Thousand Oaks, CA: Sage
Yakubovich V. 2005. Weak ties, information,
and influence: how workers find jobs in a lo?
cal Russian labor market. Am. Sociol. Rev.
70(3):408-21
Zimmerman D. 2003. Peer effects in academic
outcomes: evidence from a natural experi?
ment. Rev. Econ. Stat. 85(l):9-23
This content downloaded from 205.213.172.3 on Mon, 28 Jul 2014 10:50:23 AM
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

More Related Content

What's hot

Mining and Analyzing Academic Social Networks
Mining and Analyzing Academic Social NetworksMining and Analyzing Academic Social Networks
Mining and Analyzing Academic Social NetworksEditor IJCATR
 
Bullshiters - Who Are They And What Do We Know About Their Lives
Bullshiters - Who Are They And What Do We Know About Their LivesBullshiters - Who Are They And What Do We Know About Their Lives
Bullshiters - Who Are They And What Do We Know About Their LivesTrading Game Pty Ltd
 
Online social network mining current trends and research issues
Online social network mining current trends and research issuesOnline social network mining current trends and research issues
Online social network mining current trends and research issueseSAT Publishing House
 
Open innovation and artificial intelligence: Can OpenAI benefit humanity?
Open innovation and artificial intelligence: Can OpenAI benefit humanity?Open innovation and artificial intelligence: Can OpenAI benefit humanity?
Open innovation and artificial intelligence: Can OpenAI benefit humanity?Kasper Groes Ludvigsen
 
Crowdsourcing the Policy Cycle - Collective Intelligence 2014 Araz Taeihagh ...
Crowdsourcing the Policy Cycle - Collective Intelligence 2014 Araz  Taeihagh ...Crowdsourcing the Policy Cycle - Collective Intelligence 2014 Araz  Taeihagh ...
Crowdsourcing the Policy Cycle - Collective Intelligence 2014 Araz Taeihagh ...Araz Taeihagh
 

What's hot (7)

Policy Capacity
Policy CapacityPolicy Capacity
Policy Capacity
 
Mining and Analyzing Academic Social Networks
Mining and Analyzing Academic Social NetworksMining and Analyzing Academic Social Networks
Mining and Analyzing Academic Social Networks
 
Bullshiters - Who Are They And What Do We Know About Their Lives
Bullshiters - Who Are They And What Do We Know About Their LivesBullshiters - Who Are They And What Do We Know About Their Lives
Bullshiters - Who Are They And What Do We Know About Their Lives
 
Online social network mining current trends and research issues
Online social network mining current trends and research issuesOnline social network mining current trends and research issues
Online social network mining current trends and research issues
 
Econometric Analysis
Econometric AnalysisEconometric Analysis
Econometric Analysis
 
Open innovation and artificial intelligence: Can OpenAI benefit humanity?
Open innovation and artificial intelligence: Can OpenAI benefit humanity?Open innovation and artificial intelligence: Can OpenAI benefit humanity?
Open innovation and artificial intelligence: Can OpenAI benefit humanity?
 
Crowdsourcing the Policy Cycle - Collective Intelligence 2014 Araz Taeihagh ...
Crowdsourcing the Policy Cycle - Collective Intelligence 2014 Araz  Taeihagh ...Crowdsourcing the Policy Cycle - Collective Intelligence 2014 Araz  Taeihagh ...
Crowdsourcing the Policy Cycle - Collective Intelligence 2014 Araz Taeihagh ...
 

Similar to Causal effects of social capital

Forecasting for Managers Coursework Marking scheme - (6ECON006W)Di
Forecasting for Managers Coursework Marking scheme - (6ECON006W)DiForecasting for Managers Coursework Marking scheme - (6ECON006W)Di
Forecasting for Managers Coursework Marking scheme - (6ECON006W)DiShainaBoling829
 
^ Acadumy of Management Journal2001. Vol. 44. No. 2. 219-237.docx
^ Acadumy of Management Journal2001. Vol. 44. No. 2. 219-237.docx^ Acadumy of Management Journal2001. Vol. 44. No. 2. 219-237.docx
^ Acadumy of Management Journal2001. Vol. 44. No. 2. 219-237.docxhanneloremccaffery
 
Characteristics Of The Methodological Approach And Data...
Characteristics Of The Methodological Approach And Data...Characteristics Of The Methodological Approach And Data...
Characteristics Of The Methodological Approach And Data...Megan Espinoza
 
A SOCIAL NETWORK PERSPECTIVE ON HUMAN RESOURCES MANAGEMENT
A SOCIAL NETWORK PERSPECTIVE ON HUMAN RESOURCES MANAGEMENTA SOCIAL NETWORK PERSPECTIVE ON HUMAN RESOURCES MANAGEMENT
A SOCIAL NETWORK PERSPECTIVE ON HUMAN RESOURCES MANAGEMENTScott Faria
 
Community Evolution in the Digital Space and Creation of Social Information C...
Community Evolution in the Digital Space and Creation of SocialInformation C...Community Evolution in the Digital Space and Creation of SocialInformation C...
Community Evolution in the Digital Space and Creation of Social Information C...Saptarshi Ghosh
 
Social Networking Facebook My Space
Social Networking Facebook My SpaceSocial Networking Facebook My Space
Social Networking Facebook My Spaceannesunita
 
Hacia un método inductivo para investigar la formación de valores con respect...
Hacia un método inductivo para investigar la formación de valores con respect...Hacia un método inductivo para investigar la formación de valores con respect...
Hacia un método inductivo para investigar la formación de valores con respect...Alexandro Escudero-Nahón
 
Objectification Is A Word That Has Many Negative Connotations
Objectification Is A Word That Has Many Negative ConnotationsObjectification Is A Word That Has Many Negative Connotations
Objectification Is A Word That Has Many Negative ConnotationsBeth Johnson
 
Anti Social Behaviour Essay.pdf
Anti Social Behaviour Essay.pdfAnti Social Behaviour Essay.pdf
Anti Social Behaviour Essay.pdfRosita Cipriano
 
From Organizational to Community Creativity: Paragon Leadership & Creativity ...
From Organizational to Community Creativity: Paragon Leadership & Creativity ...From Organizational to Community Creativity: Paragon Leadership & Creativity ...
From Organizational to Community Creativity: Paragon Leadership & Creativity ...Tyler Pace
 
,ffid; ,ffiffit#.$ObjectivesnL. Describe the three basic.docx
,ffid; ,ffiffit#.$ObjectivesnL. Describe the three basic.docx,ffid; ,ffiffit#.$ObjectivesnL. Describe the three basic.docx
,ffid; ,ffiffit#.$ObjectivesnL. Describe the three basic.docxgertrudebellgrove
 
Running head LITERATURE REVIEW .docx
Running head LITERATURE REVIEW                                   .docxRunning head LITERATURE REVIEW                                   .docx
Running head LITERATURE REVIEW .docxcharisellington63520
 
Supporting user innovation activities in crowdsourcing community
Supporting user innovation activities in crowdsourcing communitySupporting user innovation activities in crowdsourcing community
Supporting user innovation activities in crowdsourcing communityMiia Kosonen
 
ilovepdf_merged.pdf- about Media and communication
ilovepdf_merged.pdf- about Media and communicationilovepdf_merged.pdf- about Media and communication
ilovepdf_merged.pdf- about Media and communicationKonulAzizli
 
Using Grounded Theory In Research
Using Grounded Theory In ResearchUsing Grounded Theory In Research
Using Grounded Theory In ResearchAlyssa Dennis
 
An Exit Strategy For The Definitional Elusiveness A Three-Dimensional Framew...
An Exit Strategy For The Definitional Elusiveness  A Three-Dimensional Framew...An Exit Strategy For The Definitional Elusiveness  A Three-Dimensional Framew...
An Exit Strategy For The Definitional Elusiveness A Three-Dimensional Framew...Ashley Hernandez
 

Similar to Causal effects of social capital (20)

Forecasting for Managers Coursework Marking scheme - (6ECON006W)Di
Forecasting for Managers Coursework Marking scheme - (6ECON006W)DiForecasting for Managers Coursework Marking scheme - (6ECON006W)Di
Forecasting for Managers Coursework Marking scheme - (6ECON006W)Di
 
^ Acadumy of Management Journal2001. Vol. 44. No. 2. 219-237.docx
^ Acadumy of Management Journal2001. Vol. 44. No. 2. 219-237.docx^ Acadumy of Management Journal2001. Vol. 44. No. 2. 219-237.docx
^ Acadumy of Management Journal2001. Vol. 44. No. 2. 219-237.docx
 
Characteristics Of The Methodological Approach And Data...
Characteristics Of The Methodological Approach And Data...Characteristics Of The Methodological Approach And Data...
Characteristics Of The Methodological Approach And Data...
 
A SOCIAL NETWORK PERSPECTIVE ON HUMAN RESOURCES MANAGEMENT
A SOCIAL NETWORK PERSPECTIVE ON HUMAN RESOURCES MANAGEMENTA SOCIAL NETWORK PERSPECTIVE ON HUMAN RESOURCES MANAGEMENT
A SOCIAL NETWORK PERSPECTIVE ON HUMAN RESOURCES MANAGEMENT
 
Community Evolution in the Digital Space and Creation of Social Information C...
Community Evolution in the Digital Space and Creation of SocialInformation C...Community Evolution in the Digital Space and Creation of SocialInformation C...
Community Evolution in the Digital Space and Creation of Social Information C...
 
Social Networking Facebook My Space
Social Networking Facebook My SpaceSocial Networking Facebook My Space
Social Networking Facebook My Space
 
Hacia un método inductivo para investigar la formación de valores con respect...
Hacia un método inductivo para investigar la formación de valores con respect...Hacia un método inductivo para investigar la formación de valores con respect...
Hacia un método inductivo para investigar la formación de valores con respect...
 
Objectification Is A Word That Has Many Negative Connotations
Objectification Is A Word That Has Many Negative ConnotationsObjectification Is A Word That Has Many Negative Connotations
Objectification Is A Word That Has Many Negative Connotations
 
Facebook psychology
Facebook psychologyFacebook psychology
Facebook psychology
 
Anti Social Behaviour Essay.pdf
Anti Social Behaviour Essay.pdfAnti Social Behaviour Essay.pdf
Anti Social Behaviour Essay.pdf
 
Exploratory Essay Example
Exploratory Essay ExampleExploratory Essay Example
Exploratory Essay Example
 
From Organizational to Community Creativity: Paragon Leadership & Creativity ...
From Organizational to Community Creativity: Paragon Leadership & Creativity ...From Organizational to Community Creativity: Paragon Leadership & Creativity ...
From Organizational to Community Creativity: Paragon Leadership & Creativity ...
 
,ffid; ,ffiffit#.$ObjectivesnL. Describe the three basic.docx
,ffid; ,ffiffit#.$ObjectivesnL. Describe the three basic.docx,ffid; ,ffiffit#.$ObjectivesnL. Describe the three basic.docx
,ffid; ,ffiffit#.$ObjectivesnL. Describe the three basic.docx
 
Running head LITERATURE REVIEW .docx
Running head LITERATURE REVIEW                                   .docxRunning head LITERATURE REVIEW                                   .docx
Running head LITERATURE REVIEW .docx
 
Supporting user innovation activities in crowdsourcing community
Supporting user innovation activities in crowdsourcing communitySupporting user innovation activities in crowdsourcing community
Supporting user innovation activities in crowdsourcing community
 
Taylor Ghost of Altmetrics Yet to Come
Taylor Ghost of Altmetrics Yet to ComeTaylor Ghost of Altmetrics Yet to Come
Taylor Ghost of Altmetrics Yet to Come
 
ilovepdf_merged.pdf- about Media and communication
ilovepdf_merged.pdf- about Media and communicationilovepdf_merged.pdf- about Media and communication
ilovepdf_merged.pdf- about Media and communication
 
Using Grounded Theory In Research
Using Grounded Theory In ResearchUsing Grounded Theory In Research
Using Grounded Theory In Research
 
An Exit Strategy For The Definitional Elusiveness A Three-Dimensional Framew...
An Exit Strategy For The Definitional Elusiveness  A Three-Dimensional Framew...An Exit Strategy For The Definitional Elusiveness  A Three-Dimensional Framew...
An Exit Strategy For The Definitional Elusiveness A Three-Dimensional Framew...
 
Research Proposal Writing
Research Proposal Writing Research Proposal Writing
Research Proposal Writing
 

Recently uploaded

Interactive Powerpoint_How to Master effective communication
Interactive Powerpoint_How to Master effective communicationInteractive Powerpoint_How to Master effective communication
Interactive Powerpoint_How to Master effective communicationnomboosow
 
CARE OF CHILD IN INCUBATOR..........pptx
CARE OF CHILD IN INCUBATOR..........pptxCARE OF CHILD IN INCUBATOR..........pptx
CARE OF CHILD IN INCUBATOR..........pptxGaneshChakor2
 
Industrial Policy - 1948, 1956, 1973, 1977, 1980, 1991
Industrial Policy - 1948, 1956, 1973, 1977, 1980, 1991Industrial Policy - 1948, 1956, 1973, 1977, 1980, 1991
Industrial Policy - 1948, 1956, 1973, 1977, 1980, 1991RKavithamani
 
BASLIQ CURRENT LOOKBOOK LOOKBOOK(1) (1).pdf
BASLIQ CURRENT LOOKBOOK  LOOKBOOK(1) (1).pdfBASLIQ CURRENT LOOKBOOK  LOOKBOOK(1) (1).pdf
BASLIQ CURRENT LOOKBOOK LOOKBOOK(1) (1).pdfSoniaTolstoy
 
mini mental status format.docx
mini    mental       status     format.docxmini    mental       status     format.docx
mini mental status format.docxPoojaSen20
 
Introduction to AI in Higher Education_draft.pptx
Introduction to AI in Higher Education_draft.pptxIntroduction to AI in Higher Education_draft.pptx
Introduction to AI in Higher Education_draft.pptxpboyjonauth
 
Activity 01 - Artificial Culture (1).pdf
Activity 01 - Artificial Culture (1).pdfActivity 01 - Artificial Culture (1).pdf
Activity 01 - Artificial Culture (1).pdfciinovamais
 
Hybridoma Technology ( Production , Purification , and Application )
Hybridoma Technology  ( Production , Purification , and Application  ) Hybridoma Technology  ( Production , Purification , and Application  )
Hybridoma Technology ( Production , Purification , and Application ) Sakshi Ghasle
 
Privatization and Disinvestment - Meaning, Objectives, Advantages and Disadva...
Privatization and Disinvestment - Meaning, Objectives, Advantages and Disadva...Privatization and Disinvestment - Meaning, Objectives, Advantages and Disadva...
Privatization and Disinvestment - Meaning, Objectives, Advantages and Disadva...RKavithamani
 
POINT- BIOCHEMISTRY SEM 2 ENZYMES UNIT 5.pptx
POINT- BIOCHEMISTRY SEM 2 ENZYMES UNIT 5.pptxPOINT- BIOCHEMISTRY SEM 2 ENZYMES UNIT 5.pptx
POINT- BIOCHEMISTRY SEM 2 ENZYMES UNIT 5.pptxSayali Powar
 
The basics of sentences session 2pptx copy.pptx
The basics of sentences session 2pptx copy.pptxThe basics of sentences session 2pptx copy.pptx
The basics of sentences session 2pptx copy.pptxheathfieldcps1
 
Measures of Central Tendency: Mean, Median and Mode
Measures of Central Tendency: Mean, Median and ModeMeasures of Central Tendency: Mean, Median and Mode
Measures of Central Tendency: Mean, Median and ModeThiyagu K
 
Advanced Views - Calendar View in Odoo 17
Advanced Views - Calendar View in Odoo 17Advanced Views - Calendar View in Odoo 17
Advanced Views - Calendar View in Odoo 17Celine George
 
Mastering the Unannounced Regulatory Inspection
Mastering the Unannounced Regulatory InspectionMastering the Unannounced Regulatory Inspection
Mastering the Unannounced Regulatory InspectionSafetyChain Software
 
Z Score,T Score, Percential Rank and Box Plot Graph
Z Score,T Score, Percential Rank and Box Plot GraphZ Score,T Score, Percential Rank and Box Plot Graph
Z Score,T Score, Percential Rank and Box Plot GraphThiyagu K
 
Beyond the EU: DORA and NIS 2 Directive's Global Impact
Beyond the EU: DORA and NIS 2 Directive's Global ImpactBeyond the EU: DORA and NIS 2 Directive's Global Impact
Beyond the EU: DORA and NIS 2 Directive's Global ImpactPECB
 
Nutritional Needs Presentation - HLTH 104
Nutritional Needs Presentation - HLTH 104Nutritional Needs Presentation - HLTH 104
Nutritional Needs Presentation - HLTH 104misteraugie
 

Recently uploaded (20)

Interactive Powerpoint_How to Master effective communication
Interactive Powerpoint_How to Master effective communicationInteractive Powerpoint_How to Master effective communication
Interactive Powerpoint_How to Master effective communication
 
CARE OF CHILD IN INCUBATOR..........pptx
CARE OF CHILD IN INCUBATOR..........pptxCARE OF CHILD IN INCUBATOR..........pptx
CARE OF CHILD IN INCUBATOR..........pptx
 
Industrial Policy - 1948, 1956, 1973, 1977, 1980, 1991
Industrial Policy - 1948, 1956, 1973, 1977, 1980, 1991Industrial Policy - 1948, 1956, 1973, 1977, 1980, 1991
Industrial Policy - 1948, 1956, 1973, 1977, 1980, 1991
 
BASLIQ CURRENT LOOKBOOK LOOKBOOK(1) (1).pdf
BASLIQ CURRENT LOOKBOOK  LOOKBOOK(1) (1).pdfBASLIQ CURRENT LOOKBOOK  LOOKBOOK(1) (1).pdf
BASLIQ CURRENT LOOKBOOK LOOKBOOK(1) (1).pdf
 
mini mental status format.docx
mini    mental       status     format.docxmini    mental       status     format.docx
mini mental status format.docx
 
Introduction to AI in Higher Education_draft.pptx
Introduction to AI in Higher Education_draft.pptxIntroduction to AI in Higher Education_draft.pptx
Introduction to AI in Higher Education_draft.pptx
 
Activity 01 - Artificial Culture (1).pdf
Activity 01 - Artificial Culture (1).pdfActivity 01 - Artificial Culture (1).pdf
Activity 01 - Artificial Culture (1).pdf
 
Hybridoma Technology ( Production , Purification , and Application )
Hybridoma Technology  ( Production , Purification , and Application  ) Hybridoma Technology  ( Production , Purification , and Application  )
Hybridoma Technology ( Production , Purification , and Application )
 
Privatization and Disinvestment - Meaning, Objectives, Advantages and Disadva...
Privatization and Disinvestment - Meaning, Objectives, Advantages and Disadva...Privatization and Disinvestment - Meaning, Objectives, Advantages and Disadva...
Privatization and Disinvestment - Meaning, Objectives, Advantages and Disadva...
 
Mattingly "AI & Prompt Design: The Basics of Prompt Design"
Mattingly "AI & Prompt Design: The Basics of Prompt Design"Mattingly "AI & Prompt Design: The Basics of Prompt Design"
Mattingly "AI & Prompt Design: The Basics of Prompt Design"
 
POINT- BIOCHEMISTRY SEM 2 ENZYMES UNIT 5.pptx
POINT- BIOCHEMISTRY SEM 2 ENZYMES UNIT 5.pptxPOINT- BIOCHEMISTRY SEM 2 ENZYMES UNIT 5.pptx
POINT- BIOCHEMISTRY SEM 2 ENZYMES UNIT 5.pptx
 
The basics of sentences session 2pptx copy.pptx
The basics of sentences session 2pptx copy.pptxThe basics of sentences session 2pptx copy.pptx
The basics of sentences session 2pptx copy.pptx
 
Staff of Color (SOC) Retention Efforts DDSD
Staff of Color (SOC) Retention Efforts DDSDStaff of Color (SOC) Retention Efforts DDSD
Staff of Color (SOC) Retention Efforts DDSD
 
Measures of Central Tendency: Mean, Median and Mode
Measures of Central Tendency: Mean, Median and ModeMeasures of Central Tendency: Mean, Median and Mode
Measures of Central Tendency: Mean, Median and Mode
 
Advanced Views - Calendar View in Odoo 17
Advanced Views - Calendar View in Odoo 17Advanced Views - Calendar View in Odoo 17
Advanced Views - Calendar View in Odoo 17
 
Mastering the Unannounced Regulatory Inspection
Mastering the Unannounced Regulatory InspectionMastering the Unannounced Regulatory Inspection
Mastering the Unannounced Regulatory Inspection
 
Z Score,T Score, Percential Rank and Box Plot Graph
Z Score,T Score, Percential Rank and Box Plot GraphZ Score,T Score, Percential Rank and Box Plot Graph
Z Score,T Score, Percential Rank and Box Plot Graph
 
INDIA QUIZ 2024 RLAC DELHI UNIVERSITY.pptx
INDIA QUIZ 2024 RLAC DELHI UNIVERSITY.pptxINDIA QUIZ 2024 RLAC DELHI UNIVERSITY.pptx
INDIA QUIZ 2024 RLAC DELHI UNIVERSITY.pptx
 
Beyond the EU: DORA and NIS 2 Directive's Global Impact
Beyond the EU: DORA and NIS 2 Directive's Global ImpactBeyond the EU: DORA and NIS 2 Directive's Global Impact
Beyond the EU: DORA and NIS 2 Directive's Global Impact
 
Nutritional Needs Presentation - HLTH 104
Nutritional Needs Presentation - HLTH 104Nutritional Needs Presentation - HLTH 104
Nutritional Needs Presentation - HLTH 104
 

Causal effects of social capital

  • 1. Estimating the Causal Effect of Social Capital: A Review of Recent Research Author(s): Ted Mouw Source: Annual Review of Sociology, Vol. 32 (2006), pp. 79-102 Published by: Annual Reviews Stable URL: http://www.jstor.org/stable/29737732 . Accessed: 28/07/2014 10:50 Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available at . http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp . JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide range of content in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and facilitate new forms of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact support@jstor.org. . Annual Reviews is collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend access to Annual Review of Sociology. http://www.jstor.org This content downloaded from 205.213.172.3 on Mon, 28 Jul 2014 10:50:23 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
  • 2. Annu. Rev. Sociol. 2006. 32:79-102 doi: 10.1146/annurev.soc.32.061604.123150 Copyright? 2006 byAnnual Reviews. All rightsreserved First published online as aReview inAdvance onApril 6, 2006 Estimating the Causal Effect of Social CAPITAL: A Review ofRecent Research TedMouw Department of Sociology, University ofNorth Carolina, Chapel Hill, North Carolina 27599; email: tedmouw@email.unc.edu Key Words peer effects, social networks, social homophily, fixed effects models ? Abstract Although thereisa largeliteratureon social capital,empirical estimates of theeffectof social capitalmay be biased because of social homophily, thetendency of similarpeople tobecome friendswith each other.Despite themethodological dif? ficulties, a recent literature has emerged across several different disciplines that tries to estimate the causal effect of social capital. This paper reviews this recent empiri? cal literature on social capital, paying close attention to the statistical and theoretical assumptions involved. Overall, there is evidence that genuine progress has been made in estimating the effect of social capital. The reviewed articles should provide useful examples for future research. INTRODUCTION The purpose of this review is to examine recent attempts to estimate the causal effectof social capital. As a number of recent authors have pointed out, there is a considerable amount of ambiguity regarding theprecise definitionof social capital (Portes 1998, Fischer 2005, Manski 2000, Kadushin 2004). The literaturethat I review focuses on what we might call "network" social capital, i.e., the effect of characteristics of friends, acquaintances, or groups on individual outcomes. Portes (1998) provides a useful definition of this form of social capital as "the ability of actors to secure benefits by virtue of theirmembership in social networks or other social structures," stressing that whereas "economic capital is in people's bank accounts and human capital is inside theirheads, social capital inheres in the structureof theirrelationships" (p. 7). The key concept here is thatsocial capital is not an individual characteristic or a personality traitbut a resource thatresides in thenetworks and groups towhich people belong. The focus on network social capital in this review is not intended to dismiss alternative definitions of social capital that stress the importance either of norms and values or of group-level outcomes. Fukuyama (1999, p. 16), for instance, pro? vides a coherent definition of social capital thatemphasizes the role of norms on group outcomes. Instead, thereason I focus on network social capital isbecause, as discussed below, theproblem of causality fornetwork social capital isparticularly 0360-0572/06/0811-0079$20.00 79 This content downloaded from 205.213.172.3 on Mon, 28 Jul 2014 10:50:23 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
  • 3. 80 MOUW clear, and it taps into an existing literatureon the role of endogenous friendship formation and self-selection in the estimation of peer effects. In addition, as re? viewed here, there is a growing body of research on network social capital and peer effects thattakes theproblem of endogeneity seriously and, I believe, makes progress inestimating the trueeffectof social capital. The papers covered in thisreview indicate thatgenuine progress can bemade in estimating thecausal effectof social capital. Although many of thepapers referto the estimation of peer effects, social interactions,or some formof neighborhood effectswithout explicit reference tosocial capital,most of thesewould be subsumed under the definition of social capital by Portes (1998) referred to above. All, however, areuseful because theypresent creativeways ofdealing with thequestion of causality under endogenous social interaction and can serve as useful examples forfutureresearch on social capital. A fundamental challenge in the estimation of the effect of social capital is posed by thecentral fact thatindividuals choose who theywant tobe friendswith andwhat groups theywant tojoin.Why does thismatter? The principle of social homophily argues thatpeople tend to choose otherswho are similar to them as friends.As a result, it is quite possible thatmuch of theestimated effectof social capital simply reflects selection effectsbased on themyriad of nonrandom ways inwhich people become friends. Of course, estimating a causal effect is difficult, ifnot impossible, with the kind of nonexperimental data thatmost social scientistswork with ingeneral, so this sortof problem is endemic in the social sciences. Given thegeneral nature of thisproblem, why shouldwe be concerned about thecausality of social capital in particular? Three reasons: First, as mentioned above, social homophily suggests a competing explanation of the social capital findings. Second, it is time; in the past decade therehas been an enormous outpouring of empirical studies on the effectof social capital on a variety of outcomes. At thispoint in thematuration of the social capital literature,it isworthwhile to ask whether we can adjudicate between alternative theories thatare also consistentwith much of the same evi? dence. As it stands,much of the literatureresorts to asserting by fiat,or by faith, thatestimates of theeffectof social capital are correctby ignoringorminimizing thepotential problems posed by nonrandom friendship formation.Third, thevery name social capital invitesa comparison to thehuman capital literature.Although some scholars have argued thatthetermsocial capital iscounterproductive because social capital is not really capital at all (Fischer 2005), thepopularity of the term is likelydue, at least inpart, to theequivalence thatitsuggestswith other formsof capital. Posing questions about causality should not be construed as picking on social capital unfairly, as the same questions have been raised regarding human capital. Justas one can argue thatestimates of theeffectof social capital arebiased because of social homophily, one can argue thatestimates of the effectof human capital onwages are biased because of unobserved factors thataffect schooling and labor market productivity (e.g., ifsmarterworkers earnmore and find iteasier to succeed This content downloaded from 205.213.172.3 on Mon, 28 Jul 2014 10:50:23 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
  • 4. CAUSAL EFFECTS OF SOCIAL CAPITAL 81 in school, then the correlation between education and earnings will partly reflect higherpay thatisdue tohighernatural ability).Economists have taken thisquestion seriously; a recent review of the causal effect of education on earnings has a bibliography listing several pages of attempts toestimate the trueeffectof human capital (Card 1999; see also Card 2001). By arguing thatsocial capital needs to confront theproblem posed by friend? ship choice, I am not arguing thatconcerns about causality should induce research paralysis, where one avoids tacklingany subject thatgoes beyond a simple descrip? tive analysis. At the same time, I am also not advocating turningto complicated statisticalmodels, such as structuralequations, as a solution for the lack of exper? imental data. As we shall see, these models make strong assumptions that cannot be tested,and theymay provide misleading estimates.Many of themost interest? ing studies reviewed below use fairly simplemethods combined with innovative use of quasi-experimental data. Researchers should be carefulwith the statistical assumptions theymake inestimating theeffectof social capital, and these assump? tions should bemade transparentto thereader, so he or she can decide thevalidity of the technique. In thenext section, I provide a brief overview of why nonrandom friendship acquisition may bias social capital models before I turnto a review of the recent literature. THE BASICPROBLEM Sobel (1995) andWinship & Sobel (2004) provide useful discussions of causality in the social sciences. Ideally, an experimental approach tocausality is preferable, manipulating one variable while holding everything else constant.When this is not possible, natural experiments and quasi-experiments provide an alternative approach. In all the literaturediscussed below, a careful understanding of the assumptions involved ineachmodeling approach iscritical, as is an understanding of thecontingent and restrictednature of the resultingcausal claims. Nonetheless, many of thepapers discussed representa substantial improvement in theestimation of theeffectof social capital. A fundamental claim of the social capital literature is that the characteristics and resources of friends,contacts, and groupsmay affect individual outcomes. For example, a positive correlation between the average characteristics of one's friends and some individual outcome is interpretedas evidence of the effect of social capital. However, because, for the most part, individuals choose their friends and thegroups theybelong to, some, ifnot all, of thepositive correlationmay simply be due to thefact thatsimilar people tend to associate with one another.There is a large literatureon theprinciple of social homophily (seeMcPherson et al. 2001 fora review), suggestingmany dimensions along which individuals with similar characteristics socialize with each other.As a result,despite the strong intuitive appeal of the importance of social capital, skepticismmay exert itsown appeal, This content downloaded from 205.213.172.3 on Mon, 28 Jul 2014 10:50:23 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
  • 5. 82 MOUW particularly for those inclined to attribute social behavior to individual choice ratherthan to social interaction (forexample, Manski 1993, pp. 531-32). Clear evidence on the role of homophily comes from longitudinal research on adolescent friendships. Kandel (1978) and Cohen (1977) use longitudinal data on adolescent friendships to show thatmuch of the similarity in attitudes and behavior among friendsorwithin cliques isdue tofriendship choice ratherthan to peer effects.Kandel (1978), for instance, studies thechange in similarity in best friends' attitudes and behavior at thebeginning and end of the school year and finds thatabout half of the increase in similarity is due to adolescents changing friendsduring thecourse of theyear ratherthan adapting theirbehavior/attitudes to resemble their initial friend.Cohen (1977, p. 237) concludes thatmost of the similarity in adolescents' attitudes isdue to initialhomophilic selection. Explicit depiction of theestimation problem posed by individual choice extends back toBlalock (1984) in sociology.Writing about contextual effects?the effect of aggregate group variables on individual outcomes?Blalock notes that "it is indeed possible thatpersons will select theircontexts on thebasis of theirown preferences" making the direction of causation difficult to determine (Blalock 1984, p. 369). Blalock stresses the importance of careful theoretical consideration to account for the relationship between individual- and group-level variables. In thecase of social capital, thispoints to the importance of a detailed understanding of how individuals choose their friends as a precursor to estimating empirical models on the effectof friends' characteristics with nonexperimental data. In a studyof theeffectof peer influences on occupational and educational aspirations, Duncan et al. (1968) recognize theproblem posed by the self-selection of friends by arguing that"if assortment on thebasis of aspirations proves tobe important, our estimates of themutual influenceof friendson each other's aspirations are not merely wrong; theybecome irrelevant" (p. 135). As discussed by Friedkin (1990), theflip side of a concern about therole of unmeasured individual characteristics on social capital effects is the impact thatunmeasured network factorsmay have on estimates of theeffectof individual variables. Although he largelyassumes thatthe networks of friends and peers are exogenous, he also considers the implications of the networks themselves being endogenous to individual characteristics and preferences (Friedkin 1990, Figure 5, p. 325).1 Moffitt (2001),Manski (1993,2000), Durlauf (2002), andDurlauf & Fafchamps (2004) all depict the difficulties of estimating social capital models under the presence of friendship,group, or neighborhood choice. Moffitt (2001) presents a particularly lucid account. He points out that theestimation problems stem from two distinct sources: simultaneous effects, in which peer or group effects are overestimated because the outcomes of friends or group members simultaneously ^oreian (2001) provides a general treatment of the question of causality in the structure of social networks. Although beyond the scope of this review, this general treatment would be useful for anyone who wanted to tryexplicitly tomodel the process of friendship formation with social network data. This content downloaded from 205.213.172.3 on Mon, 28 Jul 2014 10:50:23 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
  • 6. CAUSAL EFFECTS OF SOCIAL CAPITAL 83 effecteach other, and correlated unobservables, inwhich friendship is related to unobserved factors thatalso affect thedependent variable. Here, I present a simple model thatclarifies thebasic issues. Equation 1depicts a preference forfriendshiphomophily along twofixed char? acteristics,Xi (observed by theresearcher) andw? (unobserved). Homophily prefer? ences, i.e., the desire to associate with people who are similar to you, are expressed (forconvenience) by taking theabsolute value of thedifferencebetween potential friends' characteristics, Iijt = ~?l I*/-Xj- ?2Wi - Wj+ Sijt, 1. where e?jt is an error termand /?yfrepresents thepreference that individual ihas to choose j as a friend at time t,with higher values indicatingmore desire to be friends.2 In Equation 1, individuals who are similar in termsof x and w are more likely tobecome friends.Equation 2 depicts theoutcome F as a functionof individual characteristics and the average outcomes of one's friends, contacts, or fellow groupmembers (see Blalock 1984, p. 363, fora discussion of thismodel), Yit = ctY-it + a2x-it + o?3X? + a4w? + (pit, 2. where both Y-n (the average outcome of fs friends/groupat time /)and x_zi (the average x of f s friends/groupat time t) are possible measures of social capital. Because w, is unobserved to the researcher,what he/she ends up estimating is depicted inEquation 3: Yit = aY-it + a2x-it + a3Xi + <pit. 3. The difficulties ingettingaccurate resultsby estimatingEquation 3 can be depicted as follows. One must first address the simultaneity or reflection problem (see Manski 1993;Moffitt 2001, p. 54). If there is a social capital effectvia f_??, then it is difficult to get an accurate estimate of a ibecause all theY? s are determined simultaneously. As Manski puts it,"the problem is similar to thatof interpreting the almost simultaneous movements of a person and his reflection in a mirror_ [D]oes themirror image cause theperson's movements or reflect them?" (p. 129). With cross-sectional data, one must look for a variable to serve as an instrument for Y, i.e., something that is correlated with theFs of your friends but not your own F.With longitudinal data, it is possible to use the lagged outcomes of your friends as an instrument for their current outcomes.3 The problem of correlated unobservables occurs when there is an unobserved factor that is correlated with friendship (or group) choice and with theoutcome variable. In Equation 3, the unobserved factorw? will bias the estimate of a? 2The negative signs in front of ?i and ?2 ensure that individuals who are similar (i.e., smaller absolute differences in x and w) are more likely to become friends. 3 Ifone uses a first difference model (see Halaby 2004), the first difference of the one-period lagged outcome of your friends will be correlated, by definition, with the first difference of the error term. This content downloaded from 205.213.172.3 on Mon, 28 Jul 2014 10:50:23 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
  • 7. 84 MOUW (the coefficienton Y_it) ifw? is correlated with Yit (i.e., a4 ^ 0) and 1$ (?2 ^ 0). Similarly, theestimate ofai (thecoefficientonx_tr)will be biased ifw? iscorrelated with Xi and a4 ^ 0. How much might thismatter? Table 1presents an example of how much bias could result. In Table 1, I present results from simulated data for an imaginary school of 5000 individuals.4The resultspresented inTable 1aremerely suggestive, as they startfrom (arbitrary) known parameters and then generate the data to be analyzed. In this simulation, x? and w? are jointly normally distributedwith a correlation of0.25. InEquation 1,thevalues of ? and ?2 are set to 1.InEquation 2, ot=0, i.e., no effect of ?_,-, and a2 =a3 =a4 = l.5 As discussed above, the estimates of the coefficients for observed independent variables will be biased because of a correlated unobservable, w?.The second column ofTable 1 shows the truevalues of thecoefficients on the independent variables. Based on the results of Equation 1, each simulated student selected 10 classmates as friendswith the highest values of /#.The average values of Y and x for these 10 friends are used to calculate 7_? and X-? for Equation 2. Model 1ofTable 1 shows theordinary least square (OLS) resultsof estimating Equation 3 for this data, where ?_? and %_,- are the average y and x values for each student's 10 friends. Including F_? in themodel results ina statistically significant effect,even though the truevalue for thecoefficienton f _, is zero. In addition, the coefficienton x-? is downwardly biased. InModel 2, only theeffectsofx? and x^? are estimated, and again the social capital effect is badly biased (1.702 versus 1.0 for the truevalue). The point here is not to argue thatthese results are definitive, butmerely to suggest thateven in a very simplemodel, traditionalOLS estimates of social capital effectsmay be verymisleading. A REVIEWOF THE EMPIRICALEVIDENCEON CAUSAL EFFECTS, BYMETHOD Table 2 provides an overview of the studies reviewed in thispaper grouped by the differentmethod used. I have grouped the papers bymethod rather than by substantive topic toprovide a coherent critique of each methodological approach. The methods discussed here are fixed effectsmodels, instrumentalvariables (IVs), structural equations, randomly assigned roommates, and quasi-experimental de? signs. In each of the sections thatfollow, Iprovide a briefdiscussion of thegeneral methodological approach, followed by a detailed review of each of thedifferent papers. None of these methodological approaches is new or unique in their ap? plication to social capital models. However, as depicted inTable 2, each of the 4The data was simulated using Stata. The computer files used in the simulation are available on the author's website, http://www.tedmouw.org, for readers who wish to see the effect of changing some of the parameters. 5In both equations, the error term is normally distributed with a variance of 3. This content downloaded from 205.213.172.3 on Mon, 28 Jul 2014 10:50:23 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
  • 8. CAUSAL EFFECTS OF SOCIAL CAPITAL 85 TABLE 1 Monte-Carlo estimates of social capital with correlated unobservablesa OLS Model 1 Model 2 Fixed Effects Model 3 Cross-Lagged Regression Model 4 Model 5 Variable X; True values'3 1.0 Social capital variables: X-i X-i,t- Yu-i Constant Obs R-squared 0 1.0 N.A.C 0 0 Yi Yt AY? 0.920 0.859 (0.096)** (0.098)** 0.485 (0.039)** 0.699 1.702 1.080 (0.193)** (0.178)** (0.171)* 0.031 0.058 -0.077 (0.045) (0.045) (0.060) 5000 5000 5000 0.29 0.27 0.01 Yi 0.774 (0.094)** 1.546 (0.168)** 0.120 (0.014)** -0.026 (0.044) 5000 0.30 Yi 1.402 (0.097)* 0.262 (0.177) 0.127 (0.014)* -0.028 (0.045) 5000 0.29 aStandarderrorsinparentheses significantat 5% level;double asterisk (**) indicatessignificantat 1% level; all thecomputer filesforthisanalysis are available on theauthor'sweb page, http://www.tedmouw.org,ifreaderswish to repeat theanalysis with differentparameters. bSee Equation 2 in thetext. CN.A.,not applicable, no directeffectinEquation 2. differentapproaches makes certain assumptions, and the goal of this review is to focus attention on the relative advantages and disadvantages ofmaking these assumptions inestimating the trueeffectof social capital. Fixed EffectsModels If thebias in thesocial capitalmodel iscaused by fixed,unobserved characteristics, such as w? inEquations 1 and 2, then a "firstdifference" or fixed effectsmodel using longitudinal data can provide an unbiased estimate.Halaby (2004) provides a clear discussion of thebenefits of fixed effectsmodels vis-?-vis other estimation strategies such as random effectsand lagged dependent variables for longitudinal data. A firstdifferencemodel estimates a regression of changes in thedependent variable on changes in the independent variables for two timepoints, whereas a fixed effectsmodel uses each variable's differencefrom itswithin-individual mean. Conveniently, time-invariant variables, including unobserved ones, drop out of the model. For example, Equation 2 becomes Yit - % = ax (?_,-, - fLf) + a2 (*-,-, - *,?) + #,-? 4. This content downloaded from 205.213.172.3 on Mon, 28 Jul 2014 10:50:23 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
  • 9. 86 MOUW o+? >> & S ?* ?s c -o - S ?.? &su S S SA*3 55 ? o g ? u ^ o teM? +5 O? C s 's 2 fi wi 5 S -S? ? 'S 5 2 fi T3 +3 O ?i (Uj J> Oh^ (D .a e m IIft o cd 3 ?a t*iC tzi J3??3 <L> > ta ^ ?s <4 ? ^ a> ^ H O t? 'iJ< 3 t?O ?an" ?i ?a Co-o ine ?ffit/) .a8 fr ? t? o *h 00 H? ON cd PQ o (S O ^ o es <NOw O cd ^ 3 f Os o CO 't? O Q Isa 2| Js ? ?B e cd Ui 2J > O t? Q a) <D C ?3 Cd O O t? ^ t? O -M C <t? 13 ?2t? <u ?l o ? t? O <D te ? ? t? T3 ?S? 'S - Oh Cd |?^g?s 1iO t/i 3 > t? ai .a 11 C .2 t? Sa --S M pq -" l~l 03 O ?-tt!- <L> <D cd O P t? Oh t? 1*3?3C? -J-HcdT3 >,2 2*1 On 2 OO w OS ^ go? t/3 fe c^ ci T3 c ^ 2>?rtrsi t? Sa On =3 rafe?^ ^H t? a 'S P D to t? ^ Sf?? fi<U -jj t? cd t? <D c3 ? O? > 't? J2 ?3 3 ? g B s s 5 ??p ?2 C? J>1 This content downloaded from 205.213.172.3 on Mon, 28 Jul 2014 10:50:23 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
  • 10. CAUSAL EFFECTS OF SOCIAL CAPITAL 87 o ?5 'o *?* .^h o ? o ?? ??3 s S C rt ? * ?13<D y c? t? O <L> G ce ^ i3 "? 3 o c a) w> o X S S & ? <? M ctf <D AS S This content downloaded from 205.213.172.3 on Mon, 28 Jul 2014 10:50:23 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
  • 11. 88 MOUW where f _? and x-? axe mean values of Y-it and x-it. In Equation 4, changes in social capital over time, i.e., in Y-it and x-it, are caused by fluctuations in the composition of one's friends thatare due to theerror term inEquation 1,which isuncorrelated with thefixed, unobserved factor,w,-.A key advantage of fixed effects is thatthey allow thefixed,unobserved factor tobe correlatedwith the independent variables, whereas random effectsassume independence (Halaby 2004; Gordon et al. 2004, p. 65). The principal assumption offixed effectsmodels is thatthefixed effectsdo not change over time. Model 3 of Table 1 illustrates the accuracy of a fixed effects estimation of Equation 4, provided these assumptions hold. The data were simulated in thesame way as forModels 1 and 2, but for two timeperiods. Although xt and w, are fixed over time, the error term inEquation 1 results in change in friendship rankings over time, and hence in variation inY-it and x-it.Model 3 shows that thefixed effectsmodel provides a good estimate of the effectof x-it, as the fixed effects eliminate thefixed, unobserved effect,w?. peer effects ON education The estimate of peer effects is problematic be? cause a positive correlation between students' test scores and grade point average (GPA) could be caused by the sortingof students across schools that isbased on factorsunobserved by theresearcher.Given thehigh degree of sortingby race and class in schools in theUnited States, any cross-sectional estimate ofpeer effects is likely tobe upwardly biased. One way to tackle theproblem of endogeneity ines? timatingpeer effects is touse longitudinal data on individual students and schools to studyhow changes in the composition of schools and classes affects changes in individual students' test scores. The central problem is convincing the reader that the unobserved factors are time invariant, i.e., that changes in the composi? tionof peers are not simply a reflectionof thechanging school selectivity.Hoxby (2000), Hanushek et al. (2003), Arcidiacono & Nicholson (2005), andAngrist & Lang (2002) use fixed effectsmodels to control forfixed, unobserved factors at the school and/or individual level. Hoxby (2000) uses a rich data set from theTexas Schools Microdata Sample thatallows her tofollow individual students inmore than3000 schools from 1990 1999. She argues thatidiosyncratic changes in thegender and race composition of classrooms?differences by cohorts of students within the same school?reflect random, exogenous variation in peer composition, as parents would be unlikely to move in or out of a school district because of random, year-to-year perturbations in thedemographic composition of a classroom. Provided thatthisassumption is true, these small variations in class composition can be used to estimate peer effects. Hoxby finds significantpeer effectsbased on these essentially random fluctuations in classroom demographic composition. For example, a random 10% increase in theproportion of females in the class increases thirdgrade girls' reading scores by 0.037 points and boys' reading scores by 0.047 points,with similar effects for math scores. She notes thatthiseffectmay be due either to thefact thatgirls tend to score higher on both testsat thisage inTexas (hence, an increase in thepercentage female generates a peer effect by increasing the average test scores of students' This content downloaded from 205.213.172.3 on Mon, 28 Jul 2014 10:50:23 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
  • 12. CAUSAL EFFECTS OF SOCIAL CAPITAL 89 classmates) or to theeffect thatchanging thegender composition of theclassroom has on classroom behavior. Also using the longitudinalTexas schools data,Hanushek et al. (2003) estimate amodel of theeffectof average classmates' testscores on thechange in individual test scores. They use individual, school, and school-by-grade fixed effects.Much of the year-to-year fluctuation in theirdata is driven by annual mobility rates of students across schools of about 20%. They use classmates' test scores from two years before tomitigate what Manski (1993) calls the"reflection problem."6 Hanushek et al. (2003) find small but significantpeer effects in their full fixed effectsmodels. A one-unit increase in theaverage math score of peers (standard deviation 0.35) results ina 0.15-point increase inthechange intheaverage student's math scores (standard deviation 0.63). It isworth noting, however, that in earlier estimates of changes inmath scoreswithout the individual, school, and grade fixed effects,Hanushek et al. finda negative effectof peers' scores on individual scores (-0.07), which runs counter to thebasic intuitionabout peer effects (i.e., thatthey should be upwardly biased because of sorting).7 The Texas microdata thatHoxby (2000) and Hanushek et al. (2003) use are obviously quite remarkable and allow them to estimate models and obtain re? sults that, if taken together,aremuch more convincing thanprevious estimates of peer effects on academic achievement. Other researchwith differentdata has found differentresults,however. Angrist & Lang (2002) analyze longitudinal data on Boston's Metco program, which is a voluntary desegregation program that buses (primarily low-income, black) inner-citystudents to suburban schools. They find thatalthough the schools where theMetco students are placed experience a decline in theiraverage test scores (which has made theprogram contentious politically), thedecline is due entirely to a composition effect.They find no ev? idence of negative peer effects:The change in the scores of non-Metco students are not correlated with the number ofMetco students in the classroom. Arcidi acono & Nicholson (2005) study peer effects on medical students and find no evidence of an effectof average peerMCAT scores on fourthyear board scores after they include school fixed effects; they argue that the correlation between students' scores is due entirely to different levels of selectivity of the schools themselves. Overall, therecent evidence on peer effectsusing fixed effectsand longitudinal data ismixed. In addition, although these fixed effectsmodels are a significant improvement over cross-sectional estimates of peer effects, one must always be cautious of thepossibility thatchanges inunobserved factors such as the selectivity or desirability of the school are driving theestimates of peer effects. 6Hanushek et al. (2003) use classmates test scores from two years before to avoid building in a mechanical correlation with the dependent variable, which is the individual's change in test scores over the past year. 7One possible explanation for this negative effect is, as Hanushek et al. (2003) note, a ceiling effect on the standardized test scores. Nonetheless, it should make the reader cautious about accepting the overall results. This content downloaded from 205.213.172.3 on Mon, 28 Jul 2014 10:50:23 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
  • 13. 90 MOUW MIGRATION Social capital, in theformofmigrant networks,may provide infor? mation and help thatfacilitatesmigration. Prima facie evidence on the importance of social networks inmigration is given by thehigh rates of geographic and oc? cupational concentration among different immigrantgroups. Hagan (1998), for example, documents the role ofmigration networks in the growth of an immi? grant community inHouston. For a general depiction of the role of networks in migration, seeMassey (1993). Palloni et al. (2001) testfor the role of social capital on theprobability ofmi? gration by using sibling data from theMexican Migration Project. A high rate of migration within a family or community may represent the effect of social capital onmigration, or itmay be due to shared unmeasured characteristics. Pal? loni et al. get around thisproblem by estimatingwhat amounts to a sibling fixed effectsmodel, comparing theprobability ofmigration of individuals before and afterone of theirsiblingsmigrates. Because theirdependent variable, firstmigra? tion, is a discrete, nonrepeated event, a fixed effectsmodel similar toEquation 4 is not possible. Instead, thekey consideration of Palloni et al. is to allow for a latentvariable topick up unobserved heterogeneity in thehazard ofmigration. To see why this is important,consider the following example. Imagine a two periodmodel ofmigration with two groups of sibling pairs,A andB, inwhich the underlying probability ofmigration is higher for group A than forB (pa > Pb) If thegroup is unobserved by the researcher, theneven in the absence of social capital effects, theprobability ofmigrating inperiod twowill be higher ifyour siblingmigrated than ifhe/she did not simply because relativelymore As than Bs will have a siblingmigrate inperiod one (versus having no siblingsmigrate). Palloni et al. (2001) note that theirmodel fits the data well with only two la? tentstates, representinghigh and low unobserved migration propensities. Overall, theyfind thathaving a siblingmigrate substantially increases thehazard of the other siblingmigrating. The model is still sensitive to concerns that temporal changes, such as a local recession or drought,will increase the joint probability ofmigrating, but this is the same basic assumption thatall fixed effectsmodels make. peer effects ON delinquency Recognition of thedifficultyof differentiating between peer effectsand social homophily incriminology extends back at least to Glueck & Glueck (1950). In an analysis of thefriendsof 500 delinquent and non delinquent boys, theyfound thatthemajority of thefriendsof 98.4% of delinquent boys were delinquents, compared with only 7.4% of thefriends of nondelinquent boys. However, because theboys in the studywere selected from largely the same neighborhoods, and hence had similar opportunities toforge friendshipswith both delinquents and nondelinquents, Glueck & Glueck argued that their results re? flected the tendency that "birds of a featherflock together" and not of a causal effectof peer influence (p. 164). Gottfredson & Hirschi (1987) provide a critique of common methods of controlling for friendship selection in criminology, such as thecross-lagged regressionmodel (p. 597). This content downloaded from 205.213.172.3 on Mon, 28 Jul 2014 10:50:23 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
  • 14. CAUSAL EFFECTS OF SOCIAL CAPITAL 91 Gordon et al. (2004) use longitudinal data on gangmembership and delinquent behavior and find strongeffectsof gang membership on self-reportedbehavior of adolescents using fixed effectsmodels. Their research indicates thatthebehavior of gang members cannot be entirely attributed to the self-selection of already delinquent teens tojoin gangs, as criminal behavior increasedwhen therespondents joined thegang and declined after they leftit.Again, thebenefit of thisapproach is thatitnarrows theparameters of thedebate between peer effects and selection effects.The effectsGordon et al. (2004) reportcould be caused by theidiosyncratic changes in thedisposition tocommit delinquent acts if,say, some adolescents pass through a period when they aremore likely to commit crimes and, as a result, choose tojoin gangs, or, alternatively,by theeffectof gang membership on crime. The onlyway togo furtherin resolving thequestion is to conduct an actual social experiment or to suggest a plausible IV thatpicks up an exogenous change ingang membership. Rose et al. (1999) use data with peer and sibling reportsof smoking and find an effectof peer smoking on respondents' smoking aftercontrolling for sibling fixed effectsusing hierarchical linearmodeling (HLM). Of course, thisdoes not rule out thepossibility thatdifferences inpeer smoking levels among siblings are caused by differentfriendshippreferences among the siblings, but it is useful in indicating thattheobserved peer correlation in smoking isnot solely attributable tofixed tendencies to smoke based on shared genetic and/orhome environment among siblings.Finally, Bayer et al. (2003) use longitudinal data on 8000 juveniles serving time indifferentcorrectional institutionsinFlorida to study therole ofpeer effectson recidivism.Using fixed effectsfor thecorrectional institutiontocontrol for selectivity of assignment todifferentfacilities, theyfind that theprobability of recidivism for specific crimes varies according to the criminal histories of the peers who are serving in the same institution at the same time. labor market SOCIAL CAPITAL Mouw (2003) provides an overview and critique of the literatureon theeffectof social capital in the labormarket. He proposes an indirecttestofwhether a proposed social capital variable is trulycausal orwhether itis simplypicking up a spurious effectowing to social homophily. He shows that, ifall else is equal, workers with more social capital should be more likely touse contacts tofindwork. His results suggest thatoft-usedmeasures of labormarket social capital, such as theaverage education or job prestige of your contacts, have a spurious, rather than causal, effect on wages. This does not necessarily mean that social capital does notmatter, butmerely thatwe need tofindbettermeasures of it. Fixed effectsmodels have also been used toassess therole of social networks in the labormarket.Mouw (2002) uses longitudinal data to assess racial differences in theeffectofusing job contacts tofindwork. He finds thatwhereas black workers who used contacts have lower wages in cross-sectional models, this is not the case when one follows workers over time;workers who used contacts inone period did not do any betterwhen theydid not use contacts tofindwork. This suggests that This content downloaded from 205.213.172.3 on Mon, 28 Jul 2014 10:50:23 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
  • 15. 92 MOUW it is not theuse of contacts per se but ratherpoorer job opportunities in general (partofwhich could be due todifferences in social capital) thatcontributed to the racialwage gap. Yakubovich (2005) uses a fixed effectsapproach inan innovative way to test the "strengthofweak ties" hypothesis. He collected data onmultiple potential contacts foreach worker and found that,net of individual fixed effects, weak tieswere more likely than strong ties tohave led to a job. Although neither of thesepapers directly tests theeffectof social capital on labormarket outcomes overall, they illustratethepotential benefits of a fixed effectsapproach. Instrumental Variables and Structural Equations One solution to theproblem of correlated unobservables depicted inEquations 1-3 is tofind an IV thatis correlatedwith the independent variable of interestbut notwith theunobserved factor. InEquation 2, thiswould entail finding a variable Zi thatwas correlatedwith x? but notwith theunobserved factor,w,. The problem with this approach is thatbecause w? is unobserved, there is no way to prove thata potential Zi variable is actually a good instrument.Instead, the researcher must relyon theoretical justifications. Inmany instances, researchers have chosen instrumentson weak theoretical grounds. As Moffitt (2001) notes, "thus far the instrumentschosen have generally been ad hoc innature and notbased on a strong, or at least explicitly formulated theory" (p. 70). Ifan instrumentispoorly chosen such that it is still correlated with the error term, then the estimates may be as biased, ifnotmore so, as models thatdo not try to account for selectivity. In addition, the resultsmay depend on the researcher's arbitrary choice among a number of potential instruments,with little theoretical difference justifying the choice. Evans et al. (1992) study the effectof peer influences on teenage pregnancy using National Longitudinal Survey ofYouth (NLS Y) data, using thepercentage of students in therespondent's school who are classified as disadvantaged as their peer group measure. Preliminarymodels indicate that thepeer groupmeasure is significantly associated with the respondent's probability of teenage pregnancy, but Evans et al. provide a good discussion of why thepeer effectmay be over? estimated owing to correlated unobservables, and theyargue thatan IV approach is needed. They note that theyneed a set of IVs that are correlated with peer group characteristics and are uncorrelated with the error term on teen pregnancy. The instruments that they choose are the metropolitan area unemployment rate, median family income, poverty rate, and thepercentage of adults with a college degree. Although theynote thatthesevariables are not strongpredictors of teenage pregnancy, this does not mean that they are not correlated with the error term. This cannot be proven; itcan only be argued theoretically.The IV results show thatthe peer group effect disappears. However, the reader is left to wonder whether these variables really are good indicators of exogenous changes in peer group character? istics and what sortof biases may resultby using themas instruments.As Moffitt (2001) suggests, they seem ad hoc. The benefit of theEvans et al. (1992) paper This content downloaded from 205.213.172.3 on Mon, 28 Jul 2014 10:50:23 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
  • 16. CAUSAL EFFECTS OF SOCIAL CAPITAL 93 is that it shows therecan be a wide divergence between OLS and IV estimates, even if the IV results are based on assumptions thatmay be as problematic as the original OLS results. Structural equation models (SEMs) represent an elaboration of thebasic IV approach. SEMs are useful in dealing with problems ofmeasurement error and latentvariables with multiple indicators, both ofwhich may apply, obviously, in social capital research. They cannot, however, resolve thedebate between social capital and social homophily without making assumptions about theunderlying causal structure, assumptions that are ultimately untestable and subject to second guessing. In this sense, theymerely transformthe nature of the debate into an argument over the validity of instruments, causal diagrams, or assumptions about thedistributionof theerror term. I believe a key consideration is thattheassump? tions thataremade inorder to identifythemodel may seem innocuous to a naive reader but could turnout to have profound empirical consequences. As argued above, I believe that it is critically important that the assumptions used to iden? tifythemodel, i.e., the assumptions behind theuse of the IV, be made explicit to the reader.McDonald (1997) shows thateven with a simple data set,different, seemingly arbitraryassumptions about thepath diagram can lead to substantively different parameter estimates. With longitudinal data, a frequent approach to the endogeneity problem has been to use "cross-lagged" SEMs to tryto estimate reciprocal effects between peer selection and individual behavior. In thesemodels, measures of peer and individual behavior are regressed on laggedmeasures of both variables. Building on our previous discussion of Equations 1-4, a cross-lagged model would look like this: x-itt = bYitt- + ?>2*-*,r-i + b3Xi +et, 5. Yi,t = c Yitt-i + c2x-i,t + c&i + uu6. where x-it is theaverage value of thex?of individual fs friendsat time t(althoughx does not change, each individual's friendsmay change), and Ytis therespondent's outcome at time t.The lagged value of Y inEquation 6 is intended to control for unmeasured factors that affect Y, which in our case would be the unobserved variable wt fromEquation 2. However, Halaby (2004, pp. 52-62)8 shows thata regression on Equation 6 is not a general solution to theproblem of unobserved fixed effects (in contrast tofixed effectsmodels), nor does it solve theproblem of nonstationary, unobserved effects.9 In the presence of a fixed effect, such as wt, the 8Note that page numbers for Halaby (2004) refer to a longer, online version of the review, which may be viewed at http://www.ssc.wisc.edu/soc/faculty/pages/Ann_Revl3 total_web.pdf. 9In the case of true state dependence, taking firstdifferences of all the variables inEquation 6 will eliminate the fixed effects, but bias is still introduced because the change in the error term is correlated with the change in the lagged dependent variable. This content downloaded from 205.213.172.3 on Mon, 28 Jul 2014 10:50:23 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
  • 17. 94 MOUW lagged dependent variablewill be, by definition,correlatedwith thecomposite error term (a4Wi+ (pitfromEquation 2). As Halaby (2004) notes, "serially correlated errors in amodel with a lagged dependent variable render least squares estimates biased and inconsistent" (p. 57). Rogosa (1980) is critical of the claim of cross lagged models tomeasure reciprocal causation, showing thateven in a simple two-variable case without measurement error, the cross-lagged model may produce inconsistent results.He argues thatcross-lagged SEMs "should be set aside as a dead end" (p. 257). Models 4 and 5 ofTable 1 illustratewhat can gowrong with a lagged dependent variable. Model 4 estimates Equation 6 for the simulated data thatwere used to estimate thefixed effectsmodel inModel 3,whereas Model 5 estimates amodified formofEquation 6 where thecurrentvalue of X-it isused rather than the lagged value. The estimate of the true social capital effectx-u is badly biased in both models. Models 4 and 5 show thateven in a well-behaved, simulated example, a lagged dependent variable is not a solution for theproblem of fixed unobserved effects. Matsueda & Anderson (1998) and Schulenberg et al. (1999) use cross-lagged models to estimate peer influenceson delinquent behavior. Although both papers provide good discussions of the central issue of selection versus influence, in? spection of theproposed causal path diagrams reveals thateach ismaking strong assumptions regarding thenonexistence ofpaths between certainvariables inorder to identifythemodel. As with theEvans et al. (1992) paper, thesepapers are useful because they illustrate the range of estimates thatcan be found given semiplau? sible assumptions about themodeling strategy.Aseltine (1995) estimates a SEM of reciprocal effectsbetween peer and respondent delinquency andmarijuana use with three-wave panel data, using lagged values as IVs of the contemporaneous measures. His paper is insightfulbecause itgives a detailed account of theassump? tions thatare necessary to estimate themodel, in particular the assumption that there is no direct effectbetween lagged peer behavior and respondent behavior (i.e., itall operates via currentpeer behavior). Given Halaby's (2004) argument that lagged variables are not an adequate solution for theproblem of unobserved fixed effects,Aseltine's approach may not sufficeto takecare of thepossibility that the relationship between peer and respondent behavior is the result of correlated unobservables, i.e., the w? in Equation 2. In sum, given that one has to accept the assumption thatthepath diagram is specified correctly inorder to trusttheresults (i.e., the results of a SEM do not prove that themodel is correct), none of these papers is likely to convince skeptics thattheyhave uncovered the"true" effectof peer influence unless they can make a strong case that the assumptions they make are tenable. "Exogenous" Instrumental Variables The distinction between this section and theprevious one is amatter of degree. In some cases, the use of a particular IV may be a reasonable solution to the This content downloaded from 205.213.172.3 on Mon, 28 Jul 2014 10:50:23 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
  • 18. CAUSAL EFFECTS OF SOCIAL CAPITAL 95 endogeneity problem. In this section I discuss twopapers inwhich thisapproach seems credible. Munshi (2003) studies the effect of network size on employment among Mexican immigrantsusing rainfall patterns in origin communities as an instru? ment for network size at the destination. Munshi uses data from theMexican Migration Project (MMP) to estimate fixed effectsmodels of unemployment and occupational choice. Although theMMP is a repeated cross-sectional surveycon? ducted inMexico, ithas lifehistorydata on respondents' location and employment status. From these data, Munshi constructs person-year longitudinal data indicat? ingwhether the respondent is living inMexico or theUnited States and whether therespondentworked more thanone month during theyear (which serves as the measure of employment). For the agricultural communities in theMMP data,Munshi shows that lower levels of rainfallare empirically associated with higher numbers ofmigrants in the United States one to threeyears later. Intuitively, low rainfallwould reasonably decrease agricultural wages and make migration to theUnited States relatively more attractive.As thesemigrants establish themselves in theUnited States, they can serve as sources ofjob informationand help forsubsequentmigrantswho arrive from the same origin community.Munshi uses individual fixed effectsmodels to account forthepossibility thatrainfallaffectsthe selectivityofmigration.Migrants who anticipate poor employment prospects in theUnited Statesmightmigrate only in theevent of a drought in theirorigin community, therebydownwardly biasing models thatdo not include individual fixed effects. Inmodels inwhich rainfall is used as an IV for thenumber of established migrants from theorigin community in theUnited States,Munshi finds thatpredicted network size has a substantial effecton theemployment probability of immigrantworkers. The only problemwithMunshi's (2003) paper is thatthecalculated employment rates for themigrants in theUnited States are very high, about 95%-96%. This may be partly due to the fact that,because of data constraints,Munshi counts as employed anyone who worked at least one month in theUnited States during the calendar year.As Munshi notes, thehigh employment rates and theuse of fixed effectsmodels mean thathis results are being driven by the small percentage of migrants who were unemployed duringone year in theUnited States and employed in another year (generating variation in the dependent variable). Given that the immigrants in thedata have come to theUnited States towork andmany will have paid substantial sums ofmoney to cross theborder, it is hard tobelieve thatany of themwould spend a fullyear in theUnited States without working at least one month or thatmany would returnvoluntarily without having earned enough to recoup theexpenses of crossing theborder.Hence, it ispossible thatthe5% who are unemployed were deported before theycould work or are special cases in some otherway. In supplementalmodels, Munshi uses occupation in themost recent trip to theUnited States as a dependent variable and shows thatincreasing thenetwork size increases theprobability of securingnonagricultural employment, again using rainfall as the instrumentfor the size of themigrant network. This content downloaded from 205.213.172.3 on Mon, 28 Jul 2014 10:50:23 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
  • 19. 96 MOUW Although using the same approach inother contextsmay be difficult,Munshi's paper is a splendid example ofhow progress can bemade in social capital research by thecreative use of existing data. The unique twist to thispaper is thatit is able toexploit thegeographic distance between theorigin and destination communities to use weather as an IV Bayer et al. (2004) use census data on residential and job location fromBoston tostudy theeffectof referralnetworks on employment.They find thatworkers from differenthouseholds who live in the same census block (roughly theequivalent toa cityblock) are 50% more likely towork in the same location thanareworkers who live in the same block group but differentblocks. Because thereare, on average, tencensus blocks ineach block group in theirdata, theyargue thatthisresult isdue to the sharing of job informationamong people who live in the same geographic area. They use block-group fixed effects toaccount for thepossibility thatworkers select theirneighborhood based on unobserved factors that are also correlated with where theywork. The underlying assumption is thatthe selectivityoperates at theblock-group level but not at theblock level within block groups. Another possible interpretationof theirresults is that theyare due to reverse causality? the tendency of coworkers to share house or apartment information.They tryto account for thispossibility by restrictingsomemodels toworkers who have lived in theneighborhood forat least 2 years andwho worked less than40 weeks during theprevious year as a proxy for a spell of unemployment preceding a new job. Although census data are not ideal forpicking apart temporal order, the results seem to support their basic argument. Randomly Assigned Roommates Recently, an important literaturehas developed thatuses randomly assigned col? lege roommates as a natural experiment to estimate the effectof social capital. Although many colleges assign roommates based on answers to a listof prefer? ences (i.e., smoking/nonsmoking), provided the researcher knows theanswers to these questions, the assignment is essentially random on unobserved factors. Sacerdote (2001), Zimmerman (2003), McEwan & Soderberg (2005), and Stinebrickner & Stinebrickner (2004) (hereafter S&S) estimate models of the effectof (randomly assigned) roommate's precollege academic achievement on respondent's college GPA. The strikingresult is thatthere isno evidence of a lin? ear effectof roommate quality on college achievement. Although Sacerdote (2001) has been cited as evidence of a positive finding of peer effectsbecause he finds a positive correlation among freshman GPAs, he notes that this cannot be treated as evidence of a causal peer effect (p. 694) because of the reflectionproblem and because itmight indicatemutually experienced events. A better estimate is the relationship between roommate high school academic achievement and freshman GPA (because high school achievement is obtained prior to the common expe? rience as roommates). The coefficient of roommates' high school test scores on freshmanGPA is found tobe -.001 (s.e. 0.001) (Sacerdote 2001, model 1, table 3). This content downloaded from 205.213.172.3 on Mon, 28 Jul 2014 10:50:23 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
  • 20. CAUSAL EFFECTS OF SOCIAL CAPITAL 97 Zimmerman (2003), S&S, andMcEwan & Soderberg (2005) all find similar re? sults.10As S&S discuss, there is slight evidence of a nonlinear effect in both Sacerdote (2001) andZimmerman (2003), but theresults are not consistent across thedifferentarticles.11 What should we make of these findings? Randomly assigned roommates are, arguably, the cleanest estimates we will get of social capital effectsbecause they avoid thequestion of friendship choice thatcomplicates the restof the literature. It could be, however, that the effect is simply too small to show up; hence, the null findingswould not indicate thatsocial capital does notmatter, butmerely that thesemodels are not picking itup. In addition, S&S note thattheamount of time you spend with your roommate depends on how well you get along, and hence potential negative effectsofbad studyhabits and/orpoor academic preparation are mitigated by simply avoiding your roommate.12 S&S suggest thatmore attention should be paid to the concrete ways inwhich roommate effectsmight operate, arguing that study habits rather than achievement test scores are where a causal effectmight lie. In their study of roommates at Berea College, S&S find that although achievement scores have no effect, there is evidence of a positive effect of roommates' high schoolGPA on freshmanGPA forfemales (butnot formales), and theyclaim thatthis represents thebenefit thatstudentswith poor study skills may obtain by observing roommates with good study skills. The use of roommate data revolutionizes theestimation of social capital effects with quasi-experimental data. Clearly, it is a special situationbecause therandom assignment of roommates isundertaken by colleges forother reasons; nonetheless, this is precisely thekind of creative use of data that lends hope to the idea of estimating causal effects of social capital. At themoment, the lack of a clear finding of peer effects in these studies should give the researcher pause even if he/she is notworking in the social capital and education literature. Marmarosa & Sacerdote (2002) apply the randomly assigned roommate tech? nique to labormarket outcomes. Using data on randomly assigned freshmanyear roommates atDartmouth and informationon respondents' firstjob after college, theyfindno correlation between roommates in theprobability of receiving a high paying job. There is,however, an effectof freshmanyear hallmates' average salary 10The corresponding estimates of the linear effect of high school achievement index on freshman grades are .007 (s.e. .009) for SAT scores inMcEwan & Soderberg (2005), .007 (s.e. .006) using SAT scores in Zimmerman (2003), and .0009 (for males, s.e. .0052) to .0015 (for females, s.e. .0044) using ACT scores in S&S. 11 In a related approach, Kang (2005) studies the peer effects on education using the random assignment of students to classrooms within middle schools in Korea. Kang finds that a 1 standard deviation inpeer math scores is associated with a 0.27 standard deviation increase in students' math scores, controlling for school fixed effects. 12 Of course, once one accepts the fact that the amount of time roommates spend together, and consequently the effect they have on each other, depends on how well they get along, then this introduces some of the problem of endogeneity of friendship choice back into the model. This content downloaded from 205.213.172.3 on Mon, 28 Jul 2014 10:50:23 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
  • 21. 98 MOUW on the respondent's salary (t-statistic2.27). They conclude thatthis isdue topeer effects on career choice and help in obtaining jobs. Although this interpretation seems plausible, it is hard to reconcile thepositive finding on hallmates with the null results for roommates. Kremer & Levy (2003) and Duncan et al. (2005) study theeffectof randomly assigned roommates on grades and alcohol and drug use during college. Kremer & Levy (2003) find thatamong studentswho reporteddrinking frequently inhigh school, random assignment of a roommatewho also reporteddrinking frequently reduced the student'sGPA by a fullpoint.Duncan et al. (2005) find that,among male (butnot female) college students,iftwohigh school binge drinkers are paired together,theyaremore likely tobinge drink in college than ifa binge drinker is paired to a nonbinge drinker. Quasi-Experimental Evidence Recent evidence from theMoving toOpportunity (MTO) program can be used to estimate the role thatneighborhood effectsplay on outcomes such as work, crime, and education. The MTO program is a large-scale housing mobility exper? iment conducted infive cities. Interested families were randomly assigned to an experimental or control group. Experimental group families were given housing vouchers to live in a low-poverty neighborhood, whereas control group families did not receive the vouchers (Kling et al. 2005). Because both the experimental and control groups consist of familieswho wanted to receive housing vouchers, a comparison of theresults forfamilieswho did receive vouchers (the experimental group) and thosewho did not (thecontrol group) arguably overcomes much of the problem of correlated unobservables thatplagues the analysis of neighborhood effects. Sanbonmatsu et al. (2006) study the effect of receivingMTO housing vouchers on children's academic achievement forover 5000 children 4-7 years afterthe startof theexperiment.They find thatalthough receiving aMTO voucher resulted infamiliesmoving toneighborhoods with significantlylowerpoverty rates (33% versus 45.6% for thecontrol group), therewas no difference in thechildren's achievement test scores or measures of school or behavioral problems for any age group (p. 23). These results appear to reverse thefindings of the three-yearfol? low up of theBaltimore MTO program, which found evidence of positive results (Ludwig et al. 2005). Sanbonmatsu et al. (2006) argue that theirnull results are "particularly surprising" for the youngest children who spent a larger proportion of theirlives living in thenew neighborhood environment.They suggest thatone ex? planation for thefindings is thattheeffecton school quality of receiving vouchers, though significant,was more modest than theeffecton neighborhood poverty rates (the average percentile rank of the school on state exams was 4.1 points higher for the experimental group). At the same time, they conclude that the evidence from nonexperimental data is probably overestimated because of selection effects and thatthe true impact ofmoving families frompoor neighborhoods is probably small. The null results forchildren's outcomes are similar to themagnitude of the This content downloaded from 205.213.172.3 on Mon, 28 Jul 2014 10:50:23 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
  • 22. CAUSAL EFFECTS OF SOCIAL CAPITAL 99 findings on employment and earnings foradults (Kling et al. 2005, Ludwig et al. 2005). These MTO findings are corroborated by similar housing voucher results fromChicago (Jacob 2004). The resultsfromtheMTO program do notdirectlyaddress therole of social cap? italon theseoutcomes, as theunderlyingmechanism behind neighborhood effects is not clearly theorized ormeasured. Indeed, simplymoving to a new neighbor? hood with a lower poverty ratewill not increase your social capital unless it is accompanied by actual social integration into thenetworks of theneighborhood. Pettit& McLanahan (2003), forexample, study theeffectof residentialmobility on twomeasures of social capital in theMTO program inLos Angeles, the fre? quency thatparents talk to theparents of theirchildren's friendsand thenumber of extracurricularactivities thechild participated in.They find thata smaller percent? age of theexperimental group had talked to friends' parents over thepastmonth compared with the control group (72.7% versus 76.6%) but that thepercentage participating inactivitieswas thesame. So, a reasonable interpretationof theMTO results is thata network-based measure of social capital (talking to friends' par? ents) indicates littlechange for those familieswho moved, therebyindicating that theMTO program isnot a direct testof therole of social capital on theseoutcomes. Nonetheless, because neighborhood characteristics such as the poverty rate are of? tenused as proxies forneighborhood social capital, theMTO results suggest that we should exercise caution in interpretingtheestimated effectof thesemeasures with nonexperimental data. The randomized housing studies provide an important example of both thedifficultyand potential benefits of quasi-experimental data. CONCLUSION If individuals choose friendswho are similar to them, thenone may reasonably suspect thattheeffectsofmany social capital variables are overestimated because of unobserved, individual-level factors thatare correlated with friendship choice and theoutcome variable of interest.This is not an argument that social capital does notmatter, butmerely a suspicion thatmany existing empirical estimates of theeffectof social capital are notmuch of an improvement over our intuition or anecdotal conviction that itdoes matter. Overall, the evidence reviewed here suggests thatwhen theproblem of endogenous friendship choice is taken intoac? count by amethod thatattempts todeal with itexplicitly, theresultingestimates of social capital effects are modest in size, ranging from essentially zero for the ma? jorityof theestimates using randomly assigned roommates (see rowD ofTable 2) to the small, but significant,coefficients reported infixed effectsmodels of peer effects in education or juvenile delinquency (rowA of Table 2). Again, as de? picted in column 2 of Table 2, each of thedifferentmethodological approaches involves making certain assumptions, and the reader should be cautious about interpretingthe results ofmodels inwhich the assumptions are strong and/or not clearly explained. The evidence reviewed here, combined with the theoretical This content downloaded from 205.213.172.3 on Mon, 28 Jul 2014 10:50:23 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
  • 23. 100 MOUW argumentbehind why friendshipchoice may bias estimates of network social capi? tal, should lead social capital researchers to take theproblem of causality seriously. Munshi (2003) provides thebest example of a credible IV because, as discussed above, rainfall patterns inMexico provide a reasonably exogenous instrument for the size ofmigrant networks in theUnited States several years later,as theyaf? fect local opportunities but do not reflectchanges in opportunities in theUnited States. However, theprimary purpose of this review is to show that theproblem of nonrandom friendship choice, although posing serious problems for empirical research, is not insoluble. The literaturereviewed in thispaper addresses theen dogeneity of social capital directly and presents innovative attempts to improve the estimation of social capital effects.Although the papers reviewed here are dispersed across several disciplines and substantive topics, theircreativemethod? ological approaches may provide a useful template forfutureresearchers toarrive at amore definitive conclusion regarding theeffectof social capital on individual outcomes. The Annual Review of Sociology isonline at http://soc.annuaIreviews.org LITERATURECITED Angrist JD, Lang K. 2002. How important are classroom peer effects? Evidence from Boston's Metco Program. NBER Work. Pap. 9263, Nati. Bur. Econ. Res. http:// www.nber.org/papers/w9263 Arcidiacono P, Nicholson S. 2005. Peer effects inmedical school. J. Public Econ. 89:327-50 Aseltine RH. 1995. A reconsideration of parental and peer influences on adolescent deviance. J.Health Soc. Behav. 36 2:103-21 Bayer P, Pintoff R, Pozen DE. 2003. Build? ing criminal capital behind bars: social learning injuvenile corrections. Work. Pap. 864, Econ. Growth Cent., Yale Univ. http:// ideas. repec.org/p/egc/wpaper/864.html Bayer P, Ross SL, Topa G. 2004. Place of work and place of residence: informal hiring networks and labor market outcomes. Work. Pap. 2004-07, Dep. Econ., Univ. Conn. http:/Adeas.repec.org/p/uct/uconnp/2004-07. html Blalock. 1984. Contextual effects models: theo? retical and methodological issues. Annu. Rev. Sociol. 10:353-72 Card D. 1999. The causal effect of education on earnings. InHandbook of Labor Economics, Vol. 3, ed. O Ashenfelter, D Card, pp. 1801 63. Amsterdam: Elsevier Card D. 2001. Estimating the return to school? ing: progress on some persistent econo? metric problems. Econometrica 69(5): 1127 60 Cohen JM. 1977. Sources of peer group homo? geneity. Sociol. Educ. 50(4):227-^l Doreian P. 2001. Causality in social network analysis. Sociol. Methods Res. 30(1):81?114 Duncan G, Boisjoly J,Kremer M, Levy DM, Eccles J. 2005. Peer effects in drug use and sex among college students. /. Abnorm. Child Psychol. 33:375-85 Duncan OD, Haller AO, Portes A. 1968. Peer influences on aspirations: a reinterpretation. Am. J. Sociol. 74:119-37 Durlauf SN. 2002. On the empirics of so? cial capital. Econ. J. Royal Econ. Soc. 112(483):459-79 Durlauf SN, Fafchamps M. 2004. Social capital. NBER Work. Pap. 10485, Nati. Bur. Econ. Res. http://www.nber.org/papers/ w10485 This content downloaded from 205.213.172.3 on Mon, 28 Jul 2014 10:50:23 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
  • 24. CAUSAL EFFECTS OF SOCIAL CAPITAL 101 Evans WN, Oates WE, Schwab RM. 1992. Measuring peer effects: a study of teenage behavior. J. Polit. Econ. 100:966-91 Fischer C. 2005. Bowling alone: what's the score? Soc. Networks 27:155-67 Friedkin NE. 1990. Social networks in struc? tural equation models. Soc. Psychol. Q. 53:316-28 Fukuyama F. 1999. The Great Disruption. New York: Simon & Schuster Glueck S, Glueck E. 1950. Unraveling Juve? nile Delinquency. Cambridge, MA: Harvard Univ. Press Gordon RA, Lahey BB, Kawai E, Loeber R, Stouthamer-Loeber M, Farrington DP. 2004. Antisocial behavior and youth gang mem? bership: selection and socialization. Crimi? nology42(l):55-89 Gottfredson MR, Hirschi T. 1987. The method? ological adequacy of longitudinal research in crime and delinquency. Criminology 25:581? 614 Hagan J. 1998. Social networks, gender and im? migrant settlement: resource and constraint. Am. Sociol. Rev. 63(l):55-67 Halaby C. 2004. Panel models in sociological research: theory into practice. Annu. Rev. So? ciol. 30:507^4 Hanushek E, Kain JF, Markman JM, Rivkin SG. 2003. Does peer ability affect stu? dent achievement? J. Appl. Econometr. 18(5):527-44 Hoxby CM. 2000. Peer effects in the classroom: learning from gender and race variation. NBER Work. Pap. 7867, Nati. Bur. Econ. Res. http://papers.nber.org/papers/w7867 Jacob BA. 2004. Public housing, housing vouchers, and student achievement: evidence from public housing demolitions inChicago. Am. Econ. Rev. 94(l):233-58 Kadushin C. 2004. Too much investment in social capital? Soc. Networks 26:75 90 Kandel DB. 1978. Homophily, selection and so? cialization in adolescent friendships. Am. J. Sociol. 84:427-36 Kang C. 2005. Classroom peer effects and aca? demic achievement: quasi-randomization ev idence from South Korea. Work. Pap., Dep. Econ., Nati. Univ. Singapore Kling JR, Liebman JB, Katz LF. 2005. Ex? perimental analysis of neighborhood effects. NBER Work. Pap. 11577, Nati. Bur. Econ. Res. http://www.nber.org/papers/wl 1577 Kremer M, Levy DM. 2003. Peer effects and alcohol use among college students. NBER Work. Pap. 9876, Nati. Bur. Econ. Res. http://www.nber.org/papers/w9876 Ludwig J,Duncan G, Pinkston JC. 2005. Hous? ing mobility programs and economic self sufficiency: evidence from a randomized ex? periment. J. Public Econ. 89(1): 131-56 Manski C. 1993. Identification of endogenous social effects: the reflection problem. Rev. Econ. Stud. 60:531-42 Manski C. 2000. Economic analysis of social interactions. J. Econ. Perspect. 14:114-36 Marmarosa D, Sacerdote B. 2002. Peer and so? cial networks in job search. Eur. Econ. Rev. 46:870-79 Massey D. 1993. Theories of international mi? gration. Popul. Dev. Rev. 19(3):431-66 Matsueda RL, Anderson K. 1998. The dynam? ics of delinquent peers and delinquent behav? ior. Criminology 36:269-308 McDonald R. 1997. Haldane's lungs: a case study in path analysis. Multivar. Behav. Res. 32(l):l-38 McEwan PJ, Soderberg KA. 2005. Room? mate effects on grades: evidence from first year housing assignments. Work. Pap., Dep. Econ., Wellesley Coll. McPherson M, Smith-Lovin L, Cook JM. 2001. Birds of a feather: homophily in social net? works. Annu. Rev. Sociol. 27:415^4 Moffitt R. 2001. Policy interventions, low-level equilibria and social interactions. In Social Dynamics, ed. S Durlauf, P Young, pp. 45 82. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press Mouw T. 2002. Racial differences in the ef? fects of job contacts: conflicting evidence from cross-sectional and longitudinal data. Soc. Sei. Res. 31 (4):511-38 Mouw T. 2003. Social capital and finding a job: do contacts matter? Am. Sociol. Rev. 68:868 98 This content downloaded from 205.213.172.3 on Mon, 28 Jul 2014 10:50:23 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
  • 25. 102 MOUW Munshi K. 2003. The identification of network effects: Mexican migrants in the U.S. labor market. Q. J. Econ. 118:549-97 Palloni A, Massey D, Ceballos M, Espinosa K, Spittel M, 2001. Social capital and interna? tional migration: a test using information on family networks. Am. J. Sociol. 106:1262 98 Pettit B, McLanahan S. 2003. Residential mo? bility and children's social capital: evidence from an experiment. Soc. Sei. Q. 84(3):632 49 Portes A. 1998. Social capital: its origins and applications inmodern sociology. Annu. Rev. Sociol. 24:1-24 Rogosa DR. 1980. A critique of cross-lagged correlation. Psychol. Bull. 88:245-258 Rose JS, Chassin L, Presson CC, Sherman SJ. 1999. Peer influences on adolescent cigarette smoking: a prospective sibling anal? ysis. Merrill-Palmer Q. 45:62-79 Sacerdote B. 2001. Peer effects with random assignment: results with Dartmouth room? mates. Q. J. Econ. 116(2):681-704 Sanbonmatsu L, Kling JR,Duncan GJ, Brooks Gunn J. 2006. Neighborhoods and aca? demic achievement: results from theMov? ing to Opportunity experiment. NBER Work. Pap. 11909, Nati. Bur. Econ. Res. http://papers.nber.0rg/papers/w 11909 Schulenberg J,Maggs JL, Dielman TE, Leech SL, Kloska DD, et al. 1999. On peer influ? ences to get drunk: a panel study of young adolescents. Merrill-Palmer Q. 45:108-142 Sobel ME. 1995. Causal inference in the social and behavioral sciences. InHandbook of Sta? tistical Modeling for the Social and Behav? ioral Sciences, ed. G Arminger, CC Clogg, ME Sobel, pp. 1-38. New York: Plenum Stinebrickner T, Stinebrickner R. 2004. What can be learned about peer effects using col? lege roommates? Evidence from new sur? vey data and students from disadvantaged backgrounds. Work. Pap., Dep. Econ., Univ. Western Ontario Winship C, Sobel M. 2004. Causal inference in sociological studies. InHandbook ofData Analysis, ed. M Hardy, A Bryman, pp. 481 503. Thousand Oaks, CA: Sage Yakubovich V. 2005. Weak ties, information, and influence: how workers find jobs in a lo? cal Russian labor market. Am. Sociol. Rev. 70(3):408-21 Zimmerman D. 2003. Peer effects in academic outcomes: evidence from a natural experi? ment. Rev. Econ. Stat. 85(l):9-23 This content downloaded from 205.213.172.3 on Mon, 28 Jul 2014 10:50:23 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions