SlideShare a Scribd company logo
1 of 41
INFORMATION TECHNOLOGY, PRODUCTIVITY
GROWTH, AND REDUCED LEISURE: REVISITING
“END OF HISTORY”
Debdas Banerjee
The highly productive Information and Communications
Technology industry has sharply divided the
opinions between those who believe that it represents a radical
transformation of the capitalist order and those
who believe that it is just more of the same. This study draws
attention to a critical indicator: The balance
of work and leisure in the daily life of a worker that has
gradually evolved in the course of capitalist
development is now tilting significantly against leisure despite
productivity growth. Here, this paradox is
explained by the quality composition of knowledge workers as
well as—in contrast to what neoliberalism
makes us believe—the growing hegemony of business
organizations over that of market.
With the coming of the Industrial Revolution, work became
separated from
the home and the resolution of the work–leisure dichotomy a
social agenda. The
labor movement, in part, arose to battle against the long, rigid
workdays
imposed by the factory–system production. Their goal was to
reduce the stan-
dard workweek in order both to increase time for leisure and to
prevent the
feared technological unemployment. The shorter-hours crusade
eventually led
the governments to reform, establishing maximum hours of
work, beginning
with the English Factory Act of 1802 and more particularly the
Factory Act of
1850. However, capitals accepted it as rise in labor
productivity, or in other
words increase in per-hour productivity, compensated for fewer
hours of work in
a day or week. During the so-called “Progressive Era” (1890–
1913), several
American states limited the work hours for women and children.
The shorter-
hours movement in the U.S. culminated in the passage of the
Fair Labor
Standards Act in 1938, establishing forty hours as a standard
workweek as well
as overtime pay premium to deter employers from exceeding it.
Hence, as
industrial capitalism matured over time, work hours became
shorter, leaving
more time for leisure, social interaction, and cultural pursuits.
Workers earlier
required fewer hours to spend at the workplace to earn the
decent livelihood as
their marginal value product increased.
To a great extent, technological progress has determined the
trade-off point
between leisure and income or work. As income reaches the
level required for a
comfortable standard of living, workers put forward greater
demands (in labor
WorkingUSA: The Journal of Labor and Society · 1089-7011 ·
Volume 9 · June 2006 · pp. 199–213
© 2006 The Author(s)
Journal compilation © 2006 Immanuel Ness and Blackwell
Publishing, Inc.
negotiations) for more holidays, longer vacations, shorter work
weeks, fewer
hours per working day rather than demanding ever higher wage
rates associated
with longer working hours.1 Following productivity growth,
output market
demand was met with increased employment. If a firm wanted
more hours of
work from its existing workforce it had to pay a higher hourly
rate than the
normal wage in order to give an incentive to the individual
worker to reduce the
leisure time. With higher overtime payment, the individual is
motivated to give
up some of the leisure time because in this way she will reach a
higher utility.
However, after a critical point, the incentives do not work;
relatively low income
no longer deters absenteeism of the workers. Scandinavian
countries provide the
best examples of this. This went on from the days of Industrial
Revolution in
Britain until the end of the “golden age” of capitalism in the
1970s, or until the
beginning of the Information Age of capitalism, so to say.
The information and communications technology (ICT) was
initially
expected to take the work–leisure balance farther in favor of the
latter, as the new
technology appeared to have endogenized higher productivity.
However, gen-
erally the opposite seems to be happening. As the first shift (at
the workplace)
takes more time, the second shift (at home) becomes more
hurried and ratio-
nalized. The longer the workday at the office or plant, the more
the workers feel
pressed at home to hurry, to delegate, to delay, to forgo, to
segment, to hyper-
organize the precious remains of family time. That engages
them in a third shift:
noticing, understanding, and coping with the emotional
consequences of the
compressed second shift. On the whole, a social organization of
time that served
to synchronize the hours of work and leisure for much of the
twentieth century
is gradually disintegrating. The remarkable decline of average
hours of work per
worker over more than a century has reversed in the last two or
three decades in
all of the sectors of the economy that use computers in one form
or the other. It
is not yet clear what configuration of hours will ultimately
emerge to replace the
erstwhile standard workweek.
In the U.S. in 1977, men worked an average of forty-seven
hours and women
an average of thirty-nine hours a week. By 2002, the numbers
were at forty-nine
hours a week for men and 43.5 hours a week for women (Bond
2002). Couples,
it is found, are working longer and longer hours in the U.S., the
heartland of the
new technology. Combined work hours for dual-earner couples
with children
rose by ten hours from eighty-one hours a week in 1977 to
ninety-one hours a
week in 2002 (ibid.). Clearly, today’s working couples have less
time for their
lives off the job. Naturally, they ask: Live to work or work to
live?
Two explanations may be offered. First, on the supply side,
individuals might
have redefined the work–leisure trade-off point because the
level of income that
was earlier considered as “fair” is no longer so. It is no longer
fair because either
the social inequality has increased, thereby shifting the
reference point of com-
parison, or the same amount of work no longer, unlike in
yesteryears, fetches the
same amount of income. This of course goes against the basic
understanding
that wage is determined by productivity. Alternatively, in the
era of shrinking
social security, individuals are trying—with extra time of
work—to earn a decent
200 WORKINGUSA: THE JOURNAL OF LABOR AND
SOCIETY
livelihood after their final withdrawal from the labor market.
Hence, “work-
leisure” has become a lifetime choice of an individual, and no
longer remains a
social agenda. In which case, however, the amount of work that
had been
adequate to fetch a fair superannuating seems to be no longer so
even if labor
productivity has gone up considerably.
Second, on the demand-side, in response to increased
productivity, employ-
ers perhaps prefer longer hours of work by the existing
workforce—those that
are specially trained on-the-job—as opposed to keeping working
hours intact
and increasing employment. To them, additional employment
implies additional
costs of training for the new recruits and other transactions
costs. This however
inadequately explains the ten to twelve hours of daily work in
the call centers, or
in the data-entry jobs requiring average skills. Perhaps the lack
of legislation or
institutional measures of the type that protected the stipulated
working hours in
the shops and commercial establishments explains the
phenomenon.
Many scholars identify neoliberalism with casualization of the
workforce. By
overt as well as clandestine reforms in the existing labor laws,
the workers have
been stripped of job security, and even occupational status.
Production as well as
service organizations have been redesigning the occupations and
designations
that best suit the flexibilization program. This, in turn, takes
away many stipu-
lated rights designed for specific categories of workers. For
example, the earlier
“office clerk” is now designated as “junior management
executive,” “supervisor”
as “production executive,” “worker” as “knowledge
technologist,” and so on, and
eventually lose many of the rights the worker was entitled to so
long as the
worker was covered by the definition of “workman” under the
Industrial
Disputes Act in India, or similar other Acts elsewhere in the
world.
It is also important to recognize the changes in the interface
between market
and organization. Regulated markets were thought by the
neoliberals to have
encouraged the dominance of organization over market. In other
words, as
argued, the increase in monopoly or oligopoly during the
“golden age of capi-
talism” was an offshoot of markets regulated by various
institutional rules in
most of the countries. Deregulation has made the world flat, as
the argument
goes. However, the supremacy of the production or service
organization over the
state has been gaining more solid ground despite the theoretical
hypocrisy of
neoliberalism. The employers are now armed with renewed
sovereign powers
over their employees to deprive them of productivity gains.
Our main inquiry is focused on the paradox: new innovations
based on
microchips have unleashed immense power for productivity
growth yet the
squeeze of leisure time, increased work hours especially of the
knowledge
workers and, more significantly, reduced pay are the dominant
features of the
economy cutting across developed and developing countries.
It is argued, in this article, that (1) transition from
“disembodied” to
“embodied” technology, and (2) the changing quality of
workers, together tend
to increase the bargaining power of the knowledge workers.
However, the
reforms in the existing labor laws have engaged them in a work
condition that is
only comparable to that in the premodern industrial society. In
Section 2, the
201BANERJEE: PRODUCTIVITY AND LEISURE
distinguishing features of the skills that isolated the knowledge
workers from the
rest have been classified. The emerging relationships between
the state and the
knowledge workers are analyzed in Section 3. The paradox is
probed in Section
4. This is followed by a few concluding remarks in Section 5.
Skills That Rupture Solidarity
There are certain distinguishing characteristics of the new
technology. First,
since 1965, the power of computers as measured by the number
of transistors per
microchip has doubled every 18 months—a stupendous increase
in the process-
ing power. By the same exponential formula, a laptop that cost
US$3,000 in 1990
could cost US$6 today (Negroponte 2004, 6). But, one would
not find any US$6
laptop in the market. The problem is that the hardware in the
computer is
nonfunctional without the “logic structure of functioning”
ploughed by human
“brains” into it. This is a rather radical departure from the logic
of mechanics.
The emerging Knowledge Economy (KE) based on new
technology is
characterized by the recognition of knowledge as a source of
competitiveness,
the increasing importance of science, research, technology, and
innovation in
knowledge creation, and the use of computers and the Internet
to generate,
share, and apply knowledge. In brief, KE refers to the use of
knowledge to
produce economic benefits. A knowledge-based economy relies
primarily on the
use of ideas rather than physical abilities and on the application
of technology
rather than the transformation of raw materials. A large part of
the KE is known
as the information technology (IT) industry that encompasses
the creation,
production, distribution, purchase, and sale of IT components,
products, acces-
sories, and packaged solutions in the areas of communication,
memory, multi-
media, networking, storage and computer hardware, software,
systems, and
peripherals complemented by a host of supporting and
electronic services. This
includes software services and products, and IT-enabled
services (ITES). The
latter, in turn, includes human resource-related services such as
customer
interaction, like call centers, financial processing and
accounting, and data
management.
The use of IT assets in different sectors in the U.S., currently
the most
extensive IT user in the world, gives a fair idea of the KE—the
economy within
an economy (Table 1). Computers are, in fact, heavily
concentrated in the
services sector in the U.S., and hence the impact of IT on the
economic
performance is more visible in the latter than in other parts of
the economy.
The goods-producing sectors—agriculture, mining,
manufacturing, and
construction—are much less IT-intensive.
Thus, a knowledge worker is anyone who works for a living at
the tasks of
developing or using knowledge—someone who primarily
produces, distributes
or manipulates information rather than engages in the
manufacture of physical
products or the delivery of tangible services. In other words, a
knowledge worker
might be someone who works at any of the tasks of planning,
acquiring, search-
ing, analyzing, organizing, storing, programming, distributing,
marketing, or
202 WORKINGUSA: THE JOURNAL OF LABOR AND
SOCIETY
otherwise contributing to the transformation and commerce of
information and
those (often the same people) who work at using the knowledge
so produced.
Knowledge workers include those in the IT fields, such as
programmers, systems
analysts, technical writers, academic professionals, researchers,
and so on. The
term is also frequently used to include people outside of IT,
such as lawyers,
teachers, scientists of all kinds, and also students of all kinds.
One approach is to define knowledge workers by their
occupation. Knowl-
edge workers can also be classified according to the industry
they are employed
in. For example, the software industry requires people having
software skills
such as programming, web development, coding, designing, etc.
On the other
hand, the skill profile requirement for the ITES industry is very
different;
employees require linguistic skills and appropriate
domain/functional
experience.
The most striking growth, however, is that of “knowledge
technologists”:
computer technicians, data-entry operators, software designers,
and analysts in
clinical labs, manufacturing technologists, and paralegals
(Drucker 2001). These
people are as much manual workers as they are knowledge
workers. In fact, they
usually spend far more time working with their hands than with
their brains. But
their manual work is based on a substantial amount of
theoretical knowledge,
which can be acquired only through formal education, and not
through an
apprenticeship. They are not, as a rule, much better paid than
traditional skilled
workers are, but they see themselves as “professionals.” Just as
unskilled manual
workers in manufacturing were the dominant social and political
force in the
twentieth century, knowledge technologists are likely to become
the dominant
social—and perhaps also political—force over the next decades.
As regards the gender distribution, the share of computing
machine opera-
tors among women IT-occupation workers is significantly
higher than among
male workers. The rapid growth of the ITES sector would see a
rapid increase
in the number of women computing machine operators—the
ratio of males to
females is 35:65 among the employees in India (Nasscom
2004a). This is perhaps
Table 1. Information Technology as a Percentage of Stock of
All
Equipment and Software in Respective Sectors in the U.S., 2001
Sector %
Legal services 37
Wholesale trade 31
Business services 30
Education 27
Printing and publishing 20
Finance, insurance, real estate 18
Instruments 19
Retail trade 12.5
Health 12
Manufacturing, agriculture, electricity, gas and power,
transportation
1 to 8
Source: OECD 2004.
203BANERJEE: PRODUCTIVITY AND LEISURE
not a chance happening of the supply and demand cross, but
rather a outcome
of a deliberate decision.
The status of the knowledge workers, especially in the much-
hyped upper
ends of the IT job market, was brought to light during the IT
bubble burst in
Bangalore (India) in 2001–2002. The crash for the first time had
turned the
spotlight on labor relations and employment conditions as well
as on more
intricate aspects of the KE. The silicon-collared “professionals”
did not even
have the solace of a golden handshake like their blue-collared
brethren. The
“pink slip” phenomenon had rudely awakened them to the
inhuman and ruthless
management practices of capitalism, making them realize that
they too are wage
laborers. Some of them were forced to do hourly rated work
depending on its
availability, something worse than the condition of day
laborers. Like construc-
tion laborers, they got a job only when there was work. Job-
hopping, a favorite
pastime, was no longer the “in” thing. With every (forced) job
switchover the
wages decreased unlike before. Many workers worked in this
stifling atmo-
sphere, where every moment they were made to feel that they
were no longer
wanted. The much talked about employee stock options became
a joke after the
crash, when the shares were not worth the value of the paper
they were printed
on.
Bargaining Power of Knowledge Workers Dwarfed
Under the (Indian) Shops and Commercial Establishments Act
of 1961—
which covers IT establishments—the working hours are limited
to nine per day
and fifty-one per week. Overtime work up to 120 hours in a year
is permissible,
which is to be paid for at double the ordinary rates. No worker
is to work for
more than five hours in a day without a rest interval. The Act
provides for
one-and-a-half holidays with pay each week. According to
Section 8 of the 1961
act,
Where an employee works in any establishment for more than
nine hours in any
day or for more than forty eight hours in any week he shall in
respect of such
overtime work be entitled to wages at twice the rate of normal
wages (Shops and
Commerical Establishments Act, 1961).
In 1998, the government of India constituted the Council on
Trade and
Industry to the prime minister (with the prime minister as its
chairman). The
council subsequently constituted six Special Subject Groups,
one of which was
the “Knowledge-based industries.”2 The recommendations (in
April 2000) of
the latter task force contained a great deal on fundamental
reforms in the Shops
and Commercial Establishments Act of 1961 and Rules 1963.
The main targets
of the task force were: (1) restrictions on working hours
(Section 7 of the act); (2)
restrictions on period of work (Sections 9 and 10); (3) extra
wages for overtime
(Section 8); and (4) provisions of earned leave and sick leave
(Section 15).
204 WORKINGUSA: THE JOURNAL OF LABOR AND
SOCIETY
The argument of the task force against Section 8 of the 1961 act
was: “In
view of flexi-time the payment at double the wage rates is not
only inappropriate
but also wholly unreasonable. It is, therefore, essential that the
rule be made not
applicable to KBCs [Knowledge-based companies]” (Council on
Trade and
Industry Subject Group 2000).
This initiative by the government of India unleashed the
possibility of
exploiting the employees beyond the hours of work defined by
the 1961 act. It
also allowed or gave “official” sanctions to bypass the
obligatory payments for
overtime work. Many of the Indian states subsequently amended
their labor laws
in that spirit. The Shops and Commercial Establishments Act
became a passive
instrument once the ITES in most of the states were granted the
status of
“public utility service” providers under the Industrial Disputes
Act of 1947. In
view of the understanding of 24/365 operations, various state
governments have
classified the ITES sector as “public utility service.” Most of
the employees in
ITES organizations have thus been pushed outside the purview
of the regulating
laws that are still applicable for the blue-collared workers.
Under Section 13 of the West Bengal Shops and Commercial
Establish-
ments Act of 1963, for example, the ITES companies now have
an option of
giving compensatory day off to an employee if the quantum of
work exceeds
forty-eight hours a week. Given the round-the-clock nature of
work (which,
strictly speaking, is not true in India) that is part of the ITES
industry, the
government exempts these establishments from the following
provisions of
the act: (1) Closing an establishment and granting of a weekly
holiday
under Section 5 (1) of the act, which would enable the ITES
companies to run
their operations on all seven days of the week; (2) Opening and
closing hours
under Section 7 (1) of the act. This exemption would enable the
ITES indus-
try to run a three-shift operation; and, (3) working hours’
stipulation under
Section 7 (2) of the act, which will enable “flexitime”
operations for its
employees.
Moreover, many of the state governments in India have
permitted self-
certification, to the extent possible, of the IT industry in respect
of the following
Acts/Regulations: Payment of Wages Act, Minimum Wages Act,
Contract
Labor (regulation and abolition) Act, Workmen’s Compensation
Act, Employ-
ees State Insurance Act, and Payment of Gratuity Act, which so
far protected
workers against the whims of capitals. In other words, the IT
firms have been
allowed to remain outside the domain of regular and obligatory
inspections by
the government in matters relating to workers/employees.
In almost all of the countries having codified labor laws, it is
obligatory for
the employers to pay overtime pay premium for each hour
beyond the stipulated
hours of work. Of course, in most of the countries, this does not
apply to an
employee employed in a bonafide executive, administrative, or
professional
capacity. Being designated exempt from overtime protection
generally requires
meeting three tests: (1) the amount of salary paid must meet
minimum specified
amounts; (2) the employee must be paid a predetermined and
fixed salary, not an
hourly wage that is subject to reductions because of variations
in the quality or
205BANERJEE: PRODUCTIVITY AND LEISURE
quantity of work performed; and, (3) the employee’s job duties
must primarily
involve managerial, administrative, or professional skills.
Ironically, those days are over even though there is the euphoria
“this is a
wonderful time to be alive” (Gates 1995, 276). The U.S.
Department of Labor
adopted the regulatory changes in August 2004, which has
almost taken away the
rights of over six million workers to receive overtime pay for
longer hours of work.
The labor force is lured into the IT-job market often by such
designations as
“administrative,” “professional,” “junior management” or
“executive.” However,
they are the first and easiest to fleece; they are made ineligible
for overtime pay no
matter how low their salaries are. Millions of these workers in
the U.S. will work
longer hours at reduced pay. Changes in the primary duty test
and the redefi-
nition of “executive”—in the changed regulation—will allow
employers to deny
overtime pay to workers who do very little supervision and a
great deal of manual
and routine work. An employee who can only recommend—but
not carry
out—the “change of status” of, say, the two employees that she
“supervises” will
become an “executive” and be stripped of entitlements to
overtime pay even if
she manages nothing more substantial than a team or grouping
of employees.
Besides, it is estimated that, in the U.S., more than 900,000
employees
without a graduate degree or even a college degree are
designated as “profes-
sional employees” and lose the right to overtime pay, even if
their pay and status
fall far below that of degreed employees. As many as 2.3
million team leaders
redesignated as “administrative employees” with no supervisory
authority will
no longer be entitled to overtime pay even if they are line or
production
employees (Eisenbrey 2004). All in all, an estimated 1.4 million
low-level,
salaried supervisors will lose their overtime rights, along with
548,000 hourly
supervisors, who could be switched to being paid on a salary
basis and thus be
denied overtime protection.
The final rule codifies the worst of the federal case law, which
holds that a
low-paid Burger King assistant manager, for example, with no
authority to hire
or fire subordinates, who spends 90 percent of her time running
the cash register
and serving customers, and does not have discretionary powers,
can still be
classified as an exempt executive and be denied any pay for her
overtime hours.
Many of the occupational categories in the IT sector, in
particular, would in this
way be deprived of their existing rights although they might not
be earning
enough for their family’s adequate nutrition.
It is important to recognize that lower salary groups are also
increasingly
being put outside the purview of overtime pay. Less-skilled
employees are given
the designation of “computer programmer” and are thus made
gullible to their
right to claim extra pay for extra work hours. In the U.S., there
are about
288,700 programmers paid between US$455 a week and
US$27.63 an hour who
are affected by the changed rules. To note, a salary of US$455
per week means
an annual salary of just US$23,660, which is about US$5,000 a
year above the
poverty level for a family of four in the U.S. Moreover, the
exemption level is not
indexed for inflation in the changed regulation; it will protect
fewer and fewer
workers over time.
206 WORKINGUSA: THE JOURNAL OF LABOR AND
SOCIETY
In India, unlike in the U.S., there is no official account
available as to the
occupational wage in the IT sector. However, a survey
conducted among soft-
ware professionals working in software firms and ITES in three
representative
cities, Bangalore, Delhi/Gurgaon, and Thiruvananthapuram
(Abraham and
Sharma 2005) reveals intriguing facts about the emerging labor
market condi-
tions such as high skill intensity, rapid skill obsolescence and
continuous reskill-
ing, and highly individualized and flexible nature of wage
fixation.
The wage/salary per annum of more than 40 percent of the total
workers/
employees in different occupations in the IT and ITES is less
than or equal to
that of a lower division clerk in a public office, while the
minimum educational
qualification required for the latter is substantially lower than
that of the former.
Moreover, while the office assistants in the government offices
continue to enjoy
the benefits of overtime pay, their brethren in the IT sector look
to the elusive
“future.” Further, the per capita annual income of about 12
percent of the
software engineers was almost equal to that of a “traditional”
jute mill worker,
while 2.3 percent of them on the upper end earned more than 1.7
times the
income earned annually by a senior professor in a postgraduate
university
department. In other words, the variability of salary/wage at the
same level of
skill and in the same production process is also enormous. This
personalized
character of the labor market is bound to happen when
institutions shy away
from setting the rules of the game in the market or fail to
provide a level playing
field for all the players.
What all these add up to is “longer hours and less pay” in those
organi-
zations that are exempt, by various ways, of many of the
regulations that until
recently gave protection to workers/employees against any
unfair means of
getting jobs done. Where has melted all those neoliberal sound
bites of “open
market”? In pure competition, the theory goes, wage is
supposed to be equal
to the marginal value product of labor (MVPL). The latter is the
increase in
the value of the firm’s output resulting from hiring one extra
worker. In decid-
ing about the level of employment, the firm compares the
increase in costs
from hiring one more worker with the increase in revenue, that
is, it compares
the wage with the MVPL. However, the basic assumption is that
the firm can
obtain as much labor as it wants at the current market wage
(say, W0). So long
as the MVPL exceeds W0, the firm should increase its
employment level. If the
MVPL is less than W0, the firm should reduce employment.
Now, suppose the
workers have acquired more skills, perhaps because of “learning
by doing,”
on-the-job training, or for some other reasons. So, there is a
higher MVPL.
Employment in the firm remaining the same, the MVPL curve
will then move
outward. So now the wage ought to be higher (say, W1), in
which W0W1 is the
economic rent (see Figure 1).
The central issue is the conflict in sharing this economic rent.
The employer
complains that the trade union and the conventional labor laws
deter higher
profits and thereby capital accumulation. Because, the union
demands—as they
are empowered to do so by the existing laws—a fair proportion
of the produc-
tivity gains. So, as a countermeasure, employment is no longer
construed as a
207BANERJEE: PRODUCTIVITY AND LEISURE
person engaged for a specific duration of time as dictated by
labor laws. Follow-
ing a positive economic rent, work hours increase instead of an
increase in the
number of workers. The hourly economic rent thus flattens out,
so the claims of
the workers are invalidated. This is simple arithmetic; the
explanation is rather
complex. Anyway, no one asks: What is there for the
employers’ consortium like
Nasscom (National Association of Software and Service
Companies)?
Generally, the IT companies in India have a formal budget
allocation for
recruitment, which on an average is 7 percent of the total
employee cost
(Nasscom 2004a). However, a 7–14 percent reduction was
reported in the
allocated budget for recruitment, hiring, and orientation over
the last couple of
years. Further, 41 percent of the IT companies saw a significant
workforce
reduction (affecting 5 percent or more of the employees). In the
ITES industry
alone, 11.5 percent of the employees are affected (Nasscom
2004b). Neverthe-
less, the rate of growth in the Indian IT industry continued to be
positive
(Nasscom 2004a). The conclusion is obvious: longer hours of
work and less pay.
Moreover, there is infringement upon the freedom of the
employees to move
out for better pay and/or service conditions. The current
attrition rate in the
industry is estimated at about 25–40 percent (Nasscom 2004a).
Because of the
costs associated with attrition levels, including investment in
employee training
etc., as alleged, a number of Indian IT firms have colluded
against workers and
started taking measures to limit attrition. Some of these
measures include: (1)
nonhiring of applicants who spent less than a year at their
previous workplace or
those who have changed three jobs in two years; (2) blacklisting
of agencies who
are actively involved in poaching candidates; and, (3) ensuring
that candidates
produce official release letters from the previous employer at
the time of their
appointment (ibid.). The knowledge workers are thus made
captive, a parallel of
which one may find, so to say, in the tea or rubber plantations
in the nineteenth
and early twentieth centuries.
M
V
P
L
, w
ag
e
W 0
E
MVPL
L* Employment
E'
W 1
L'
MVPL'
Figure 1. Wage, Productivity, and Employment.
208 WORKINGUSA: THE JOURNAL OF LABOR AND
SOCIETY
Decoding the Paradox
Information and Communication Technology-based network of
computers,
especially the personal computers (PCs), which was initially in
the 1960s meant
for the defense establishments in the U.S. to integrate the
university research
departments into a network, became available for mass use and
application in the
early 1980s. The ICT productivity-led resurgence has close
similarities with
the general-purpose technology that emerged in the 1920s in the
form of the
dynamo and the electrification of the industrial economy that
drastically
increased labor productivity and reduced fixed capital costs. It
is important to
recognize that, in the 1960s, ICT was not hailed as revolution.
Thomas Savery
(Britain) invented the steam engine in 1698. However, it very
slowly came into
industrial use only half a century later and became almost
synonymous with the
English Industrial Revolution. The productivity crisis of
capitalism in the 1970s
similarly unlocked tremendous economic possibilities for the
ICT technology
of the previous decades. The emergence of the microprocessor
and the diffusion
of the PC, with their immediate possibility of distributed
information storage
and processing, set the stage for a radical change under a set of
economic and
social preconditions. Semiconductors are getting faster,
computer memories are
expanding, and ICT prices are falling. Data transmission costs
have fallen
dramatically and continue to fall, bandwidth is growing, and
Internet hosts are
expanding and multiplying. Cellular phone usage is growing
worldwide, adding
to the pace and capacity for change and innovation.
The contribution of IT to aggregate productivity growth
appeared to be
disembodied initially.3 Rapid technological progress within the
IT-producing
industry itself raised the level of the general-purpose
technology, and any firm
could garner the benefits and make differences in
competitiveness. Countries
where the business sector has been quick in shifting resources
toward the ICT
industry and in adopting highly productive ICT equipment have
been able to reap
higher output and productivity growth rates (Cohen, Garibaldi,
and Scarpetta
2004). In the latter half of the 1990s, things began to take new
shapes. Productivity
growth that embodies knowledge, know-how, and software
assumed importance.
Productivity improvement is no longer the property of just new
capital invest-
ment (cf. Solow 1960). And, market leadership rather depends
to a great extent on
developing distinguishing software and/or distinguishing
computer programs.
Growth in labor productivity is an aggregate outcome of three
factors,
namely, capital deepening, increase in labor quality, and
increase in total factor
productivity (TFP) (i.e., that part of the output growth that
cannot be explained
by increase in either capital or labor but by technological
change). Jorgenson and
Stiroh (2000) show that TFP in the Information Age, especially
during the latter
half of the 1990s in the U.S., had been quite high and
comparable to that during
1959–1973. Capitalism somehow has recovered from the crisis
that it faced in
the 1970s.
The repeat economic slowdown during 2000–2003, however, has
challenged
the emerging idea that the business cycle perhaps has come to
an end, resulting
209BANERJEE: PRODUCTIVITY AND LEISURE
from the spread of ICT. In the U.S., net stock (at current cost)
of private fixed
assets of the type “IT equipment and software”—in the
nonresidential sector—
increased at an annual average rate of 3.8 percent, from
US$1,238 billion in
2000 to US$1,383 billion in 2003 (U.S. Department of
Commerce, Bureau of
Economic Analysis, Fixed Asset Table, 2005). Increase in
“real” investments is
particularly noteworthy in the context of rapidly falling ICT
prices. The deep-
ening of capital notwithstanding the economy experienced a
slowdown.
There are two explanations to the investment–output
“mismatch.” First, the
distinguishing characteristic of investments in the IT sector is
that it cannot be
equated with the earlier manufacturing investments. The
unrelenting require-
ments of an increasingly short product–replacement cycle in the
IT sector have
complicated the productivity scenario. A large part of the
outlays on fixed
technology costs is written off quickly. The high rate of
technological progress
resulted in a corresponding high rate of obsolescence of fixed
capital. For
instance, in the year 1995 before Windows 95 was introduced to
the market by
Microsoft, a 486 PC with 4–8 MB of random access memory,
much lower
capacity hard disk drive than that required by Windows 95
operating system
(OS), and a much lower color resolution of the video monitor,
were the optimal
mix of capital equipment. Within a span of just ten years, a
series of changes in
the OS—useful or useless—has been rendering the computer
hardware includ-
ing the video monitor obsolescent in quick succession. It is not
that all those
changes led to higher and higher productivity. But because the
earlier software
product support services are withdrawn, the consumers are
rather forced to go
in for the newer configuration of the hardware.
Those who expected miracles to happen out of this technology
are at a loss.
Although surging demands for new IT capital have boosted
overall capital
spending growth, the nation’s capital stock has not been
growing at a similar
rate. An estimate shows that 60 percent of annual corporate IT
budgets go
toward the replacement of outdated equipment and increasingly
frequent
product upgrades (Roach 1998). Besides, the underutilization of
the capacity of
IT capital stock in the economy has increased spectacularly.4
Second, in analyzing labor productivity, we have to go beyond
the simple
fact that the quality of labor (à la Gary Becker)—in the core IT
sector—has
vastly improved through formal education. The firm that tracks
worker produc-
tivity does so through fairly simple standards: hours per day or
week on job,
revenue or sales per employee, customer retention, and
customer transactions
per hour or day. Less popular, more industry-specific methods
include measur-
ing productivity by product cycles, net profit per employee,
time from concept
to working prototype, and factory output. The notion of
comparing input with
output is also pertinent for the software developer. The measure
most com-
monly used is: “size” as a ratio of “effort.” Size is normally
measured using lines
of code and effort per person days or months. Thus,
productivity is equal to the
lines of code per person months. The simplicity of the equation
hides the
problem of measuring effort. When a person states that they
spent a day on
the project it does not state whether this was 8, 12, or 16 hours.
Many knowledge
210 WORKINGUSA: THE JOURNAL OF LABOR AND
SOCIETY
workers are now on the job much longer than the official data
would suggest.
The transition from industrial capitalism to “digital” capitalism,
from the era of
the dominating rule of the Factory Act to that of the Shops and
Commercial
Establishments Act, is also a passage from accounting for the
work of the worker
in terms of day(s) to hour(s)—the fearful broadening of the
accountability of the
knowledge workers.
However, increasing the productivity of knowledge workers is
going to be
far more difficult to achieve than previous productivity
breakthroughs for blue-
collar and agricultural workers. Revolutions were all about
sustained productiv-
ity growth in the creation of tangible products by improving the
efficiency of
tangible production techniques. “Increase the speed of the
conveyor belt in the
assembly shop, the productivity of the workers would
automatically increase” is
the bygone era. By contrast, the supposed breakthroughs of the
Information Age
hinge more on an intangible knowledge-based product that is
largely the result
of an equally intangible human thought process (Roach 1998).
The productivity growth in ICT manufacturing (say, computer
hardware) is
much faster than that in ICT using sectors (say, in computer
software develop-
ment) where labor input tends to be cerebral and much more
difficult to replace
with a machine. The Hicks–Marshall prototype of capital–labor
substitution has
thus become archaic in the KE. The limitations on boosting the
cerebral effi-
ciency of the knowledge worker have made it extremely
difficult to raise their
hourly productivity. At the point when ICT is introduced in an
enterprise, one
would find a leap forward in productivity, and then it flattens.
The problem
really is to sustain at least the initial rate of productivity
increase. So, the rate of
increase in output now depends on lengthening the working
hours, given the
number of employees. Thus, surfing the World Wide Web,
performing after-
hours banking, or hooking up to the office network from home,
hotel, or airport
waiting lounge have snatched larger time commitment from the
knowledge
workers. The latter has been legitimized by the reformed labor
laws that bid
farewell to the long-cherished democratic rights of the workers.
Conclusion
The specific nature of IT so far as the productivity part of it is
considered has
notionally strengthened the bargaining strength of the
knowledge workers. But
why the knowledge workers have not been able to resist the
gradual erosion of
the leisure time could be explained by (a) falling income per
hour of work,
and/or, (b) lack of State protection for the non-unionized
workers.
In the U.S., the hourly wage rate in the IT sector is found to be
highest among
“Computer systems analyst and scientist” in the year 2003.
However, the hourly
wage rate for “Physics teacher, postsecondary,” “Lawyer and
Judge,” “Sociology
teacher, postsecondary,” “Teacher, college and university,” or
“History teacher,
postsecondary” was much higher than the “computer systems
analyst” (USDOL
2003). If the hourly wage rate was proportional to hourly value
addition in all the
economic activities, the “computer systems analyst,” in
particular, and the IT
211BANERJEE: PRODUCTIVITY AND LEISURE
occupations, in general, seem to be lagging behind many other
knowledge
workers as well as manufacturing occupations in terms of labor
productivity.
Based on the experience of the U.S. labor market, the
disproportionality in the
Indian labor market, especially in the IT sector, seems to have a
converging trend
and the wages afterwards would follow a downward curve as the
supply situation
of “specific skills” improve. Once the supply situation
improves, which is very
likely in the near future—which Nasscom predicts will take
place in 2008—the
wage differentials would automatically reduce and stabilize.
Further, Indian vendors are likely to face increased competition
from global
vendors. Some of the advantages global companies have over
Indian companies
include: established customer relationships, robust training
models, security
systems for data privacy, business continuity plans, and deeper
understanding of
client businesses and business environments, especially in the
U.K. and U.S.
(Nasscom 2004a, 75). Besides, the influx of new vendors in the
Indian IT sector
and the subsequent increase in competition, along with the
shrinkage in the
dollar-output market may cause significant price undercutting,
leading to
increasing pressure on margins, and, in turn, on the greatest
source of added
value in the industry, that is, the knowledge workers.
However, while many other knowledge (e.g., the teachers) as
well as blue-
collar workers would continue to enjoy many of the basic rights
at work, the
nonunionized IT workers including the knowledge technologists
who see them-
selves as “professionals” but not much better paid than
traditional skilled
workers, and the majority of whom are women, would remain
deprived of
collective representation. This whole situation reminds us of the
plight of the
factory workers in the early days of the English Industrial
Revolution (Marx
1887, chap. 10, “The Working-Day”; Thompson 1963, chap. 6),
and the his-
torical path that the working class traversed over the last two
centuries. Perhaps,
there is no “End of History” (à la Francis Fukuyama 1992).
Debdas Banerjee is Professor of Economics at the Institute of
Development
Studies Kolkata, West Bengal, India. He is the author of
Globalization, Industrial
Restructuring and Labour Standards: Where India Meets the
Global, published by
Sage Publications in 2005. Address correspondence to Dr.
Debdas Banerjee,
Calcutta University Alipore Campus, Block A, 5th Floor, 1
Reformatory Street,
Kolkata 700027, INDIA. Facsimile: +91 33 2448-1364. E-mail:
[email protected]
idsk.org.
Notes
1. There is the general agreement that the supply curve of labor
by single individuals exhibits the backward-
bending pattern, although economists disagree as to the shape of
the aggregate supply of labor. The idea is
that as the standard of living increases people find that unless
they have the time to enjoy leisure activities,
it is not worth their while to work harder in order to obtain the
higher income required for more leisure.
2. Knowledge-based companies are typically engaged in the
areas such as software development, consultancy,
pharmaceuticals, financial services, engineering services,
biotechnology, etc.
212 WORKINGUSA: THE JOURNAL OF LABOR AND
SOCIETY
3. That is, acquisition of external technology in the form of
patents, nonpatented inventions, licences,
disclosure of know-how, trademarks, designs, patterns and
computer and other scientific and technical
services related to the implementation of technological product
and process innovations, plus the acquisi-
tion of packaged software.
4. Quite often very sophisticated high-performance PCs are used
just for word processing or Internet surfing.
References
Abraham, V., and R. K. Sharma. 2005. New technology and the
emerging labor market: A study of Indian IT
industry. Indian Journal of Labor Economics 48 (4):789–802.
Banerjee, D. 2005. Globalization, industrial restructuring and
labor standards: Where India meets the global. New
Delhi, London and Thousand Oaks, CA: Sage Publications.
Bond, J. T. 2002. The national study of the changing workforce.
With E. Galinsky, D. Prottas, and C.
Thompson. Report No. 3, Families and Work Institute, New
York.
Cohen, D., P. Garibaldi, and S. Scarpetta. 2004. The ICT
revolution: Productivity differences and the digital divide.
New York: Oxford University Press.
Drucker, P. 2001. The next society. The Economist, November
01.
Eisenbrey, R. 2004. Longer hours, less pay. Briefing Paper No.
152, Economic Policy Institute, Washington,
DC.
Fukuyama, F. 1992. The end of history and the last man. New
York: Free Press.
Gates, B. 1995. The road ahead. New York: Viking.
Government of India, Prime Minister’s Council on Trade and
Industry. Subject Group on Knowledge-based
Industries. 2000. “Recommendations of the Task Force on
Knowledge-Based Industries.” Annexure V:
Labor Legislation. April, New Delhi.
http://indiaimage.nic.in/pmcouncils/reports/knowl/ (accessed
July
27, 2005).
Jorgenson, D. W., and K. J. Stiroh. 2000. Raising the speed
limit: U.S. economic growth in the information
age. Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 1:125–211.
Marx, K. 1887. Capital. Vol. 1. Moscow, Russia: Foreign
Languages Publishing House.
National Association of Software and Service Companies
(Nasscom). 2004a. Strategic review. New Delhi,
India: Nasscom.
Nasscom. 2004b. Nasscom Hewitt total rewards study. New
Delhi, India: Nasscom.
Negroponte, N. 2004. Hack out the useless extras. New
Scientist, June 5.
OECD. 2004. Understanding economic growth. Paris: OECD.
Roach, S. S. 1998. No productivity boom for workers. Issues in
Science and Technology 14 (4):49–56.
Solow, R. M. 1960. Investment and technical progress. In
Mathematical methods in social sciences, ed. K. J. Arrow,
S. Karlin, and P. Suppes, Stanford: Stanford University Press.
Thompson, E. P. 1963. The making of the English working
class. Harmondsworth, England: Penguin Books.
United States Department of Commerce. Bureau of Economic
Analysis. 2005. Fixed Assets Table. Washington,
DC: United States Department of Commerce, Bureau of
Economic Analysis. http://www.bls.gov
(accessed August 2005).
United States Department of Labor (USDOL). Bureau of Labor
Statistics. 2003. National Compensation Survey
2003. Washington, DC: United States Department of Labor,
Bureau of Labor Statistics. http://
www.bls.gov (accessed August 2005).
213BANERJEE: PRODUCTIVITY AND LEISURE
http://indiaimage.nic.in/pmcouncils/reports/knowl
http://www.bls.gov
http://www.bls.gov
http://www.bls.gov
Assignment
Course / Subject: PUBLIC ADMINISTRATION
Assignment Topic: Evaluation of Agency’s Human Resources
Management for (ASPA) American Society of Public
Administrators
As a consultant, you need to develop an in-depth analysis and
evaluation of the selected agency’s human resources
management system and processes and then provide
recommendations for improvement. Therefore, you will conduct
interviews with agency representatives and research related
academic sources and Websites. The analysis will be read by the
VP of Accounts and Client Support as well as by the leaders of
the agency for whom you are working.
Write a five to six (5-6) page paper in which you:
Analyze three to four (3-4) of the major components of the
agency’s human resource system, processes, and performance
evaluation plan for hiring and retaining a diversified workforce.
(Title this section Human Resource Processes.)
Analyze and describe the implications impacting the agency’s
current employment trend, growth, and delivery of its products
and services. (Title this section Implications of Human
Resource Workforce.)
Recommend two to three (2-3) managerial and professional
skills and competencies required to improve the agency’s
workforce by explaining each recommendation, providing
reasons each recommendation would bring about improvement,
providing two to three (2-3) ways the agency could implement
programs in preparation for those skills not visible within the
agency’s workforce as a method of promotion and advancement
for current employees. (Title this section Succession Planning
for Human Resource Management.)
Describe the consultant position you are performing by (a)
giving it a title; (b) explaining two to three (2-3) major
specifications required of the job and how each will be
measured in a performance evaluation; and by (c) explaining
two to three (2-3) ways this position will be used within the
various departments of the agency and for meeting the specific
goals / objectives of the agency. (This job description will be
provided to the Agency Director who has requested it. As a
resource, you are to use the Dictionary of Occupational Titles,
located at http://www.occupationalinfo.org/ and published by
the U. S. Department of Labor located at www.usajobs.gov.
(Title this section Job Analysis and Design.)
Provide proof of one to two (1-2) interviews submitting the
completed interview form with a list of questions for and
responses from each interviewee. (Put this in the Appendix
under Interview Forms.)
Provide four to five (4-5) relevant and credible outside
resources that support the content of this assignment. (Include
no more than one (1) non-government Website.)
Your assignment must follow these formatting requirements:
Be typed, double spaced, using Times New Roman font (size
12), with one-inch margins on all sides; citations and references
must follow APA format. Check with your professor for any
additional instructions.
Include a cover page containing the title of the assignment, the
student’s name, the professor’s name, the course title, and the
date. The sections must have appropriate titles. The cover page,
reference page, and appendix pages are not included in the
required assignment page length. The assignment must be
submitted as a Microsoft Word document.

More Related Content

Similar to INFORMATION TECHNOLOGY, PRODUCTIVITYGROWTH, AND REDUCED LEIS.docx

Industrial Revolution- The Changed Britain
Industrial Revolution- The Changed BritainIndustrial Revolution- The Changed Britain
Industrial Revolution- The Changed BritainJevish Sydamah
 
Standardized Testing Flaws
Standardized Testing FlawsStandardized Testing Flaws
Standardized Testing FlawsKaty Allen
 
seguridad .pdf
seguridad .pdfseguridad .pdf
seguridad .pdfFredisin
 
A Matter of Time - The Rise of Zero Hours Contracts
A Matter of Time - The Rise of Zero Hours ContractsA Matter of Time - The Rise of Zero Hours Contracts
A Matter of Time - The Rise of Zero Hours ContractsMiqui Mel
 
Future of work An initial perspective by Andrew Curry of The Futures Company
Future of work  An initial perspective by Andrew Curry of The Futures CompanyFuture of work  An initial perspective by Andrew Curry of The Futures Company
Future of work An initial perspective by Andrew Curry of The Futures CompanyFuture Agenda
 
February 2012 Newsletter Pacific Advisors
February 2012 Newsletter Pacific AdvisorsFebruary 2012 Newsletter Pacific Advisors
February 2012 Newsletter Pacific Advisorsmpitkin
 
Serving Workers in the Gig Economy
Serving Workers in the Gig EconomyServing Workers in the Gig Economy
Serving Workers in the Gig Economypeter86868
 
IWG plc research report: the future of work
IWG plc research report: the future of workIWG plc research report: the future of work
IWG plc research report: the future of workAlyceTyler
 
Four Day Workweek Policy For Improving Employment and Environmental Condition...
Four Day Workweek Policy For Improving Employment and Environmental Condition...Four Day Workweek Policy For Improving Employment and Environmental Condition...
Four Day Workweek Policy For Improving Employment and Environmental Condition...Sociotechnical Roundtable
 
Cody I. Smith: Gender Disparities in the Peripheral and Core Sectors of the ...
Cody I. Smith: Gender Disparities in the Peripheral and Core Sectors  of the ...Cody I. Smith: Gender Disparities in the Peripheral and Core Sectors  of the ...
Cody I. Smith: Gender Disparities in the Peripheral and Core Sectors of the ...Cody Smith
 
Ch. 8 Employment, Labor, And Wages
Ch. 8 Employment, Labor, And WagesCh. 8 Employment, Labor, And Wages
Ch. 8 Employment, Labor, And Wagesbenefieldshannon
 
Various stages of industrial revolution
Various stages of industrial revolution Various stages of industrial revolution
Various stages of industrial revolution vedjain3
 
Connecting And Engaging Teams In A Distributed Workforce
Connecting And Engaging Teams In A Distributed WorkforceConnecting And Engaging Teams In A Distributed Workforce
Connecting And Engaging Teams In A Distributed WorkforceCitrix Online
 
IKnowledge workers are now untethered, able to perform tas
IKnowledge workers are now untethered, able to perform tasIKnowledge workers are now untethered, able to perform tas
IKnowledge workers are now untethered, able to perform tasMalikPinckney86
 
An uncertain future - interview with Professor Robert Reich, Goldman School ...
An uncertain future -  interview with Professor Robert Reich, Goldman School ...An uncertain future -  interview with Professor Robert Reich, Goldman School ...
An uncertain future - interview with Professor Robert Reich, Goldman School ...The Economist Media Businesses
 
The McGregor Theory Essay
The McGregor Theory EssayThe McGregor Theory Essay
The McGregor Theory EssayNicole Fields
 

Similar to INFORMATION TECHNOLOGY, PRODUCTIVITYGROWTH, AND REDUCED LEIS.docx (20)

Industrial Revolution- The Changed Britain
Industrial Revolution- The Changed BritainIndustrial Revolution- The Changed Britain
Industrial Revolution- The Changed Britain
 
Standardized Testing Flaws
Standardized Testing FlawsStandardized Testing Flaws
Standardized Testing Flaws
 
seguridad .pdf
seguridad .pdfseguridad .pdf
seguridad .pdf
 
EDX Artefact.docx
EDX Artefact.docxEDX Artefact.docx
EDX Artefact.docx
 
A Matter of Time - The Rise of Zero Hours Contracts
A Matter of Time - The Rise of Zero Hours ContractsA Matter of Time - The Rise of Zero Hours Contracts
A Matter of Time - The Rise of Zero Hours Contracts
 
Future of work An initial perspective by Andrew Curry of The Futures Company
Future of work  An initial perspective by Andrew Curry of The Futures CompanyFuture of work  An initial perspective by Andrew Curry of The Futures Company
Future of work An initial perspective by Andrew Curry of The Futures Company
 
February 2012 Newsletter Pacific Advisors
February 2012 Newsletter Pacific AdvisorsFebruary 2012 Newsletter Pacific Advisors
February 2012 Newsletter Pacific Advisors
 
Serving Workers in the Gig Economy
Serving Workers in the Gig EconomyServing Workers in the Gig Economy
Serving Workers in the Gig Economy
 
IWG plc research report: the future of work
IWG plc research report: the future of workIWG plc research report: the future of work
IWG plc research report: the future of work
 
Four Day Workweek Policy For Improving Employment and Environmental Condition...
Four Day Workweek Policy For Improving Employment and Environmental Condition...Four Day Workweek Policy For Improving Employment and Environmental Condition...
Four Day Workweek Policy For Improving Employment and Environmental Condition...
 
Cody I. Smith: Gender Disparities in the Peripheral and Core Sectors of the ...
Cody I. Smith: Gender Disparities in the Peripheral and Core Sectors  of the ...Cody I. Smith: Gender Disparities in the Peripheral and Core Sectors  of the ...
Cody I. Smith: Gender Disparities in the Peripheral and Core Sectors of the ...
 
Ch. 8 Employment, Labor, And Wages
Ch. 8 Employment, Labor, And WagesCh. 8 Employment, Labor, And Wages
Ch. 8 Employment, Labor, And Wages
 
W9443
W9443W9443
W9443
 
Various stages of industrial revolution
Various stages of industrial revolution Various stages of industrial revolution
Various stages of industrial revolution
 
Connecting And Engaging Teams In A Distributed Workforce
Connecting And Engaging Teams In A Distributed WorkforceConnecting And Engaging Teams In A Distributed Workforce
Connecting And Engaging Teams In A Distributed Workforce
 
IKnowledge workers are now untethered, able to perform tas
IKnowledge workers are now untethered, able to perform tasIKnowledge workers are now untethered, able to perform tas
IKnowledge workers are now untethered, able to perform tas
 
pm133
pm133pm133
pm133
 
An uncertain future - interview with Professor Robert Reich, Goldman School ...
An uncertain future -  interview with Professor Robert Reich, Goldman School ...An uncertain future -  interview with Professor Robert Reich, Goldman School ...
An uncertain future - interview with Professor Robert Reich, Goldman School ...
 
OrgStrategiesChapter2007
OrgStrategiesChapter2007OrgStrategiesChapter2007
OrgStrategiesChapter2007
 
The McGregor Theory Essay
The McGregor Theory EssayThe McGregor Theory Essay
The McGregor Theory Essay
 

More from dirkrplav

InstructionsW4 Nightingale Case A & B – 35 points - Individual A.docx
InstructionsW4 Nightingale Case A & B – 35 points - Individual A.docxInstructionsW4 Nightingale Case A & B – 35 points - Individual A.docx
InstructionsW4 Nightingale Case A & B – 35 points - Individual A.docxdirkrplav
 
InstructionsView CAAE Stormwater video Too Big for Our Ditches.docx
InstructionsView CAAE Stormwater video Too Big for Our Ditches.docxInstructionsView CAAE Stormwater video Too Big for Our Ditches.docx
InstructionsView CAAE Stormwater video Too Big for Our Ditches.docxdirkrplav
 
InstructionsTITLEF14-2Beginning an 8-column work sheet for a merch.docx
InstructionsTITLEF14-2Beginning an 8-column work sheet for a merch.docxInstructionsTITLEF14-2Beginning an 8-column work sheet for a merch.docx
InstructionsTITLEF14-2Beginning an 8-column work sheet for a merch.docxdirkrplav
 
InstructionsUse and add the real life situation provided below t.docx
InstructionsUse and add the real life situation provided below t.docxInstructionsUse and add the real life situation provided below t.docx
InstructionsUse and add the real life situation provided below t.docxdirkrplav
 
InstructionsThe objective of this assessment is to demonstrate y.docx
InstructionsThe objective of this assessment is to demonstrate y.docxInstructionsThe objective of this assessment is to demonstrate y.docx
InstructionsThe objective of this assessment is to demonstrate y.docxdirkrplav
 
InstructionsThis assignment will be checked using anti-plagia.docx
InstructionsThis assignment will be checked using anti-plagia.docxInstructionsThis assignment will be checked using anti-plagia.docx
InstructionsThis assignment will be checked using anti-plagia.docxdirkrplav
 
instructionss.docxjust to make sure againi need u to ext.docx
instructionss.docxjust to make sure againi need u to ext.docxinstructionss.docxjust to make sure againi need u to ext.docx
instructionss.docxjust to make sure againi need u to ext.docxdirkrplav
 
InstructionsProvide an analysis of the affects of the publics.docx
InstructionsProvide an analysis of the affects of the publics.docxInstructionsProvide an analysis of the affects of the publics.docx
InstructionsProvide an analysis of the affects of the publics.docxdirkrplav
 
InstructionsProblem #Point ValueYour Points14243446526167484915101.docx
InstructionsProblem #Point ValueYour Points14243446526167484915101.docxInstructionsProblem #Point ValueYour Points14243446526167484915101.docx
InstructionsProblem #Point ValueYour Points14243446526167484915101.docxdirkrplav
 
InstructionsPlease answer the following question in a minimum.docx
InstructionsPlease answer the following question in a minimum.docxInstructionsPlease answer the following question in a minimum.docx
InstructionsPlease answer the following question in a minimum.docxdirkrplav
 
InstructionsMy report is about the future of work and focuses the .docx
InstructionsMy report is about the future of work and focuses the .docxInstructionsMy report is about the future of work and focuses the .docx
InstructionsMy report is about the future of work and focuses the .docxdirkrplav
 
InstructionsInstructions for the Microsoft Excel TemplatesThis wor.docx
InstructionsInstructions for the Microsoft Excel TemplatesThis wor.docxInstructionsInstructions for the Microsoft Excel TemplatesThis wor.docx
InstructionsInstructions for the Microsoft Excel TemplatesThis wor.docxdirkrplav
 
InstructionsResearch and write a brief answer to the following .docx
InstructionsResearch and write a brief answer to the following .docxInstructionsResearch and write a brief answer to the following .docx
InstructionsResearch and write a brief answer to the following .docxdirkrplav
 
Instructionsinstructions.docxFinal Lab ReportYou are requ.docx
Instructionsinstructions.docxFinal Lab ReportYou are requ.docxInstructionsinstructions.docxFinal Lab ReportYou are requ.docx
Instructionsinstructions.docxFinal Lab ReportYou are requ.docxdirkrplav
 
INSTRUCTIONSInstructionsPlease evaluate, display, and interpret t.docx
INSTRUCTIONSInstructionsPlease evaluate, display, and interpret t.docxINSTRUCTIONSInstructionsPlease evaluate, display, and interpret t.docx
INSTRUCTIONSInstructionsPlease evaluate, display, and interpret t.docxdirkrplav
 
InstructionsEach of your 2 replies must contain at least .docx
InstructionsEach of your 2 replies must contain at least .docxInstructionsEach of your 2 replies must contain at least .docx
InstructionsEach of your 2 replies must contain at least .docxdirkrplav
 
InstructionsInstructions for numberguessernumberGuesser.html.docx
InstructionsInstructions for numberguessernumberGuesser.html.docxInstructionsInstructions for numberguessernumberGuesser.html.docx
InstructionsInstructions for numberguessernumberGuesser.html.docxdirkrplav
 
InstructionsI need 3 pages of the four questions. That is abo.docx
InstructionsI need 3 pages of the four questions. That is abo.docxInstructionsI need 3 pages of the four questions. That is abo.docx
InstructionsI need 3 pages of the four questions. That is abo.docxdirkrplav
 
InstructionsFor this assignment, collect data exhibiting a relat.docx
InstructionsFor this assignment, collect data exhibiting a relat.docxInstructionsFor this assignment, collect data exhibiting a relat.docx
InstructionsFor this assignment, collect data exhibiting a relat.docxdirkrplav
 
InstructionsFor this week’s assignment, you will synthesize the .docx
InstructionsFor this week’s assignment, you will synthesize the .docxInstructionsFor this week’s assignment, you will synthesize the .docx
InstructionsFor this week’s assignment, you will synthesize the .docxdirkrplav
 

More from dirkrplav (20)

InstructionsW4 Nightingale Case A & B – 35 points - Individual A.docx
InstructionsW4 Nightingale Case A & B – 35 points - Individual A.docxInstructionsW4 Nightingale Case A & B – 35 points - Individual A.docx
InstructionsW4 Nightingale Case A & B – 35 points - Individual A.docx
 
InstructionsView CAAE Stormwater video Too Big for Our Ditches.docx
InstructionsView CAAE Stormwater video Too Big for Our Ditches.docxInstructionsView CAAE Stormwater video Too Big for Our Ditches.docx
InstructionsView CAAE Stormwater video Too Big for Our Ditches.docx
 
InstructionsTITLEF14-2Beginning an 8-column work sheet for a merch.docx
InstructionsTITLEF14-2Beginning an 8-column work sheet for a merch.docxInstructionsTITLEF14-2Beginning an 8-column work sheet for a merch.docx
InstructionsTITLEF14-2Beginning an 8-column work sheet for a merch.docx
 
InstructionsUse and add the real life situation provided below t.docx
InstructionsUse and add the real life situation provided below t.docxInstructionsUse and add the real life situation provided below t.docx
InstructionsUse and add the real life situation provided below t.docx
 
InstructionsThe objective of this assessment is to demonstrate y.docx
InstructionsThe objective of this assessment is to demonstrate y.docxInstructionsThe objective of this assessment is to demonstrate y.docx
InstructionsThe objective of this assessment is to demonstrate y.docx
 
InstructionsThis assignment will be checked using anti-plagia.docx
InstructionsThis assignment will be checked using anti-plagia.docxInstructionsThis assignment will be checked using anti-plagia.docx
InstructionsThis assignment will be checked using anti-plagia.docx
 
instructionss.docxjust to make sure againi need u to ext.docx
instructionss.docxjust to make sure againi need u to ext.docxinstructionss.docxjust to make sure againi need u to ext.docx
instructionss.docxjust to make sure againi need u to ext.docx
 
InstructionsProvide an analysis of the affects of the publics.docx
InstructionsProvide an analysis of the affects of the publics.docxInstructionsProvide an analysis of the affects of the publics.docx
InstructionsProvide an analysis of the affects of the publics.docx
 
InstructionsProblem #Point ValueYour Points14243446526167484915101.docx
InstructionsProblem #Point ValueYour Points14243446526167484915101.docxInstructionsProblem #Point ValueYour Points14243446526167484915101.docx
InstructionsProblem #Point ValueYour Points14243446526167484915101.docx
 
InstructionsPlease answer the following question in a minimum.docx
InstructionsPlease answer the following question in a minimum.docxInstructionsPlease answer the following question in a minimum.docx
InstructionsPlease answer the following question in a minimum.docx
 
InstructionsMy report is about the future of work and focuses the .docx
InstructionsMy report is about the future of work and focuses the .docxInstructionsMy report is about the future of work and focuses the .docx
InstructionsMy report is about the future of work and focuses the .docx
 
InstructionsInstructions for the Microsoft Excel TemplatesThis wor.docx
InstructionsInstructions for the Microsoft Excel TemplatesThis wor.docxInstructionsInstructions for the Microsoft Excel TemplatesThis wor.docx
InstructionsInstructions for the Microsoft Excel TemplatesThis wor.docx
 
InstructionsResearch and write a brief answer to the following .docx
InstructionsResearch and write a brief answer to the following .docxInstructionsResearch and write a brief answer to the following .docx
InstructionsResearch and write a brief answer to the following .docx
 
Instructionsinstructions.docxFinal Lab ReportYou are requ.docx
Instructionsinstructions.docxFinal Lab ReportYou are requ.docxInstructionsinstructions.docxFinal Lab ReportYou are requ.docx
Instructionsinstructions.docxFinal Lab ReportYou are requ.docx
 
INSTRUCTIONSInstructionsPlease evaluate, display, and interpret t.docx
INSTRUCTIONSInstructionsPlease evaluate, display, and interpret t.docxINSTRUCTIONSInstructionsPlease evaluate, display, and interpret t.docx
INSTRUCTIONSInstructionsPlease evaluate, display, and interpret t.docx
 
InstructionsEach of your 2 replies must contain at least .docx
InstructionsEach of your 2 replies must contain at least .docxInstructionsEach of your 2 replies must contain at least .docx
InstructionsEach of your 2 replies must contain at least .docx
 
InstructionsInstructions for numberguessernumberGuesser.html.docx
InstructionsInstructions for numberguessernumberGuesser.html.docxInstructionsInstructions for numberguessernumberGuesser.html.docx
InstructionsInstructions for numberguessernumberGuesser.html.docx
 
InstructionsI need 3 pages of the four questions. That is abo.docx
InstructionsI need 3 pages of the four questions. That is abo.docxInstructionsI need 3 pages of the four questions. That is abo.docx
InstructionsI need 3 pages of the four questions. That is abo.docx
 
InstructionsFor this assignment, collect data exhibiting a relat.docx
InstructionsFor this assignment, collect data exhibiting a relat.docxInstructionsFor this assignment, collect data exhibiting a relat.docx
InstructionsFor this assignment, collect data exhibiting a relat.docx
 
InstructionsFor this week’s assignment, you will synthesize the .docx
InstructionsFor this week’s assignment, you will synthesize the .docxInstructionsFor this week’s assignment, you will synthesize the .docx
InstructionsFor this week’s assignment, you will synthesize the .docx
 

Recently uploaded

Details on CBSE Compartment Exam.pptx1111
Details on CBSE Compartment Exam.pptx1111Details on CBSE Compartment Exam.pptx1111
Details on CBSE Compartment Exam.pptx1111GangaMaiya1
 
80 ĐỀ THI THỬ TUYỂN SINH TIẾNG ANH VÀO 10 SỞ GD – ĐT THÀNH PHỐ HỒ CHÍ MINH NĂ...
80 ĐỀ THI THỬ TUYỂN SINH TIẾNG ANH VÀO 10 SỞ GD – ĐT THÀNH PHỐ HỒ CHÍ MINH NĂ...80 ĐỀ THI THỬ TUYỂN SINH TIẾNG ANH VÀO 10 SỞ GD – ĐT THÀNH PHỐ HỒ CHÍ MINH NĂ...
80 ĐỀ THI THỬ TUYỂN SINH TIẾNG ANH VÀO 10 SỞ GD – ĐT THÀNH PHỐ HỒ CHÍ MINH NĂ...Nguyen Thanh Tu Collection
 
diagnosting testing bsc 2nd sem.pptx....
diagnosting testing bsc 2nd sem.pptx....diagnosting testing bsc 2nd sem.pptx....
diagnosting testing bsc 2nd sem.pptx....Ritu480198
 
Andreas Schleicher presents at the launch of What does child empowerment mean...
Andreas Schleicher presents at the launch of What does child empowerment mean...Andreas Schleicher presents at the launch of What does child empowerment mean...
Andreas Schleicher presents at the launch of What does child empowerment mean...EduSkills OECD
 
How to Add a Tool Tip to a Field in Odoo 17
How to Add a Tool Tip to a Field in Odoo 17How to Add a Tool Tip to a Field in Odoo 17
How to Add a Tool Tip to a Field in Odoo 17Celine George
 
What is 3 Way Matching Process in Odoo 17.pptx
What is 3 Way Matching Process in Odoo 17.pptxWhat is 3 Way Matching Process in Odoo 17.pptx
What is 3 Way Matching Process in Odoo 17.pptxCeline George
 
OSCM Unit 2_Operations Processes & Systems
OSCM Unit 2_Operations Processes & SystemsOSCM Unit 2_Operations Processes & Systems
OSCM Unit 2_Operations Processes & SystemsSandeep D Chaudhary
 
How to Manage Website in Odoo 17 Studio App.pptx
How to Manage Website in Odoo 17 Studio App.pptxHow to Manage Website in Odoo 17 Studio App.pptx
How to Manage Website in Odoo 17 Studio App.pptxCeline George
 
Observing-Correct-Grammar-in-Making-Definitions.pptx
Observing-Correct-Grammar-in-Making-Definitions.pptxObserving-Correct-Grammar-in-Making-Definitions.pptx
Observing-Correct-Grammar-in-Making-Definitions.pptxAdelaideRefugio
 
HMCS Vancouver Pre-Deployment Brief - May 2024 (Web Version).pptx
HMCS Vancouver Pre-Deployment Brief - May 2024 (Web Version).pptxHMCS Vancouver Pre-Deployment Brief - May 2024 (Web Version).pptx
HMCS Vancouver Pre-Deployment Brief - May 2024 (Web Version).pptxmarlenawright1
 
Spring gala 2024 photo slideshow - Celebrating School-Community Partnerships
Spring gala 2024 photo slideshow - Celebrating School-Community PartnershipsSpring gala 2024 photo slideshow - Celebrating School-Community Partnerships
Spring gala 2024 photo slideshow - Celebrating School-Community Partnershipsexpandedwebsite
 
Ernest Hemingway's For Whom the Bell Tolls
Ernest Hemingway's For Whom the Bell TollsErnest Hemingway's For Whom the Bell Tolls
Ernest Hemingway's For Whom the Bell TollsPallavi Parmar
 
8 Tips for Effective Working Capital Management
8 Tips for Effective Working Capital Management8 Tips for Effective Working Capital Management
8 Tips for Effective Working Capital ManagementMBA Assignment Experts
 
MuleSoft Integration with AWS Textract | Calling AWS Textract API |AWS - Clou...
MuleSoft Integration with AWS Textract | Calling AWS Textract API |AWS - Clou...MuleSoft Integration with AWS Textract | Calling AWS Textract API |AWS - Clou...
MuleSoft Integration with AWS Textract | Calling AWS Textract API |AWS - Clou...MysoreMuleSoftMeetup
 
QUATER-1-PE-HEALTH-LC2- this is just a sample of unpacked lesson
QUATER-1-PE-HEALTH-LC2- this is just a sample of unpacked lessonQUATER-1-PE-HEALTH-LC2- this is just a sample of unpacked lesson
QUATER-1-PE-HEALTH-LC2- this is just a sample of unpacked lessonhttgc7rh9c
 
COMMUNICATING NEGATIVE NEWS - APPROACHES .pptx
COMMUNICATING NEGATIVE NEWS - APPROACHES .pptxCOMMUNICATING NEGATIVE NEWS - APPROACHES .pptx
COMMUNICATING NEGATIVE NEWS - APPROACHES .pptxannathomasp01
 
HMCS Max Bernays Pre-Deployment Brief (May 2024).pptx
HMCS Max Bernays Pre-Deployment Brief (May 2024).pptxHMCS Max Bernays Pre-Deployment Brief (May 2024).pptx
HMCS Max Bernays Pre-Deployment Brief (May 2024).pptxEsquimalt MFRC
 
UChicago CMSC 23320 - The Best Commit Messages of 2024
UChicago CMSC 23320 - The Best Commit Messages of 2024UChicago CMSC 23320 - The Best Commit Messages of 2024
UChicago CMSC 23320 - The Best Commit Messages of 2024Borja Sotomayor
 
When Quality Assurance Meets Innovation in Higher Education - Report launch w...
When Quality Assurance Meets Innovation in Higher Education - Report launch w...When Quality Assurance Meets Innovation in Higher Education - Report launch w...
When Quality Assurance Meets Innovation in Higher Education - Report launch w...Gary Wood
 
REMIFENTANIL: An Ultra short acting opioid.pptx
REMIFENTANIL: An Ultra short acting opioid.pptxREMIFENTANIL: An Ultra short acting opioid.pptx
REMIFENTANIL: An Ultra short acting opioid.pptxDr. Ravikiran H M Gowda
 

Recently uploaded (20)

Details on CBSE Compartment Exam.pptx1111
Details on CBSE Compartment Exam.pptx1111Details on CBSE Compartment Exam.pptx1111
Details on CBSE Compartment Exam.pptx1111
 
80 ĐỀ THI THỬ TUYỂN SINH TIẾNG ANH VÀO 10 SỞ GD – ĐT THÀNH PHỐ HỒ CHÍ MINH NĂ...
80 ĐỀ THI THỬ TUYỂN SINH TIẾNG ANH VÀO 10 SỞ GD – ĐT THÀNH PHỐ HỒ CHÍ MINH NĂ...80 ĐỀ THI THỬ TUYỂN SINH TIẾNG ANH VÀO 10 SỞ GD – ĐT THÀNH PHỐ HỒ CHÍ MINH NĂ...
80 ĐỀ THI THỬ TUYỂN SINH TIẾNG ANH VÀO 10 SỞ GD – ĐT THÀNH PHỐ HỒ CHÍ MINH NĂ...
 
diagnosting testing bsc 2nd sem.pptx....
diagnosting testing bsc 2nd sem.pptx....diagnosting testing bsc 2nd sem.pptx....
diagnosting testing bsc 2nd sem.pptx....
 
Andreas Schleicher presents at the launch of What does child empowerment mean...
Andreas Schleicher presents at the launch of What does child empowerment mean...Andreas Schleicher presents at the launch of What does child empowerment mean...
Andreas Schleicher presents at the launch of What does child empowerment mean...
 
How to Add a Tool Tip to a Field in Odoo 17
How to Add a Tool Tip to a Field in Odoo 17How to Add a Tool Tip to a Field in Odoo 17
How to Add a Tool Tip to a Field in Odoo 17
 
What is 3 Way Matching Process in Odoo 17.pptx
What is 3 Way Matching Process in Odoo 17.pptxWhat is 3 Way Matching Process in Odoo 17.pptx
What is 3 Way Matching Process in Odoo 17.pptx
 
OSCM Unit 2_Operations Processes & Systems
OSCM Unit 2_Operations Processes & SystemsOSCM Unit 2_Operations Processes & Systems
OSCM Unit 2_Operations Processes & Systems
 
How to Manage Website in Odoo 17 Studio App.pptx
How to Manage Website in Odoo 17 Studio App.pptxHow to Manage Website in Odoo 17 Studio App.pptx
How to Manage Website in Odoo 17 Studio App.pptx
 
Observing-Correct-Grammar-in-Making-Definitions.pptx
Observing-Correct-Grammar-in-Making-Definitions.pptxObserving-Correct-Grammar-in-Making-Definitions.pptx
Observing-Correct-Grammar-in-Making-Definitions.pptx
 
HMCS Vancouver Pre-Deployment Brief - May 2024 (Web Version).pptx
HMCS Vancouver Pre-Deployment Brief - May 2024 (Web Version).pptxHMCS Vancouver Pre-Deployment Brief - May 2024 (Web Version).pptx
HMCS Vancouver Pre-Deployment Brief - May 2024 (Web Version).pptx
 
Spring gala 2024 photo slideshow - Celebrating School-Community Partnerships
Spring gala 2024 photo slideshow - Celebrating School-Community PartnershipsSpring gala 2024 photo slideshow - Celebrating School-Community Partnerships
Spring gala 2024 photo slideshow - Celebrating School-Community Partnerships
 
Ernest Hemingway's For Whom the Bell Tolls
Ernest Hemingway's For Whom the Bell TollsErnest Hemingway's For Whom the Bell Tolls
Ernest Hemingway's For Whom the Bell Tolls
 
8 Tips for Effective Working Capital Management
8 Tips for Effective Working Capital Management8 Tips for Effective Working Capital Management
8 Tips for Effective Working Capital Management
 
MuleSoft Integration with AWS Textract | Calling AWS Textract API |AWS - Clou...
MuleSoft Integration with AWS Textract | Calling AWS Textract API |AWS - Clou...MuleSoft Integration with AWS Textract | Calling AWS Textract API |AWS - Clou...
MuleSoft Integration with AWS Textract | Calling AWS Textract API |AWS - Clou...
 
QUATER-1-PE-HEALTH-LC2- this is just a sample of unpacked lesson
QUATER-1-PE-HEALTH-LC2- this is just a sample of unpacked lessonQUATER-1-PE-HEALTH-LC2- this is just a sample of unpacked lesson
QUATER-1-PE-HEALTH-LC2- this is just a sample of unpacked lesson
 
COMMUNICATING NEGATIVE NEWS - APPROACHES .pptx
COMMUNICATING NEGATIVE NEWS - APPROACHES .pptxCOMMUNICATING NEGATIVE NEWS - APPROACHES .pptx
COMMUNICATING NEGATIVE NEWS - APPROACHES .pptx
 
HMCS Max Bernays Pre-Deployment Brief (May 2024).pptx
HMCS Max Bernays Pre-Deployment Brief (May 2024).pptxHMCS Max Bernays Pre-Deployment Brief (May 2024).pptx
HMCS Max Bernays Pre-Deployment Brief (May 2024).pptx
 
UChicago CMSC 23320 - The Best Commit Messages of 2024
UChicago CMSC 23320 - The Best Commit Messages of 2024UChicago CMSC 23320 - The Best Commit Messages of 2024
UChicago CMSC 23320 - The Best Commit Messages of 2024
 
When Quality Assurance Meets Innovation in Higher Education - Report launch w...
When Quality Assurance Meets Innovation in Higher Education - Report launch w...When Quality Assurance Meets Innovation in Higher Education - Report launch w...
When Quality Assurance Meets Innovation in Higher Education - Report launch w...
 
REMIFENTANIL: An Ultra short acting opioid.pptx
REMIFENTANIL: An Ultra short acting opioid.pptxREMIFENTANIL: An Ultra short acting opioid.pptx
REMIFENTANIL: An Ultra short acting opioid.pptx
 

INFORMATION TECHNOLOGY, PRODUCTIVITYGROWTH, AND REDUCED LEIS.docx

  • 1. INFORMATION TECHNOLOGY, PRODUCTIVITY GROWTH, AND REDUCED LEISURE: REVISITING “END OF HISTORY” Debdas Banerjee The highly productive Information and Communications Technology industry has sharply divided the opinions between those who believe that it represents a radical transformation of the capitalist order and those who believe that it is just more of the same. This study draws attention to a critical indicator: The balance of work and leisure in the daily life of a worker that has gradually evolved in the course of capitalist development is now tilting significantly against leisure despite productivity growth. Here, this paradox is explained by the quality composition of knowledge workers as well as—in contrast to what neoliberalism makes us believe—the growing hegemony of business organizations over that of market. With the coming of the Industrial Revolution, work became separated from the home and the resolution of the work–leisure dichotomy a social agenda. The labor movement, in part, arose to battle against the long, rigid workdays imposed by the factory–system production. Their goal was to reduce the stan- dard workweek in order both to increase time for leisure and to prevent the feared technological unemployment. The shorter-hours crusade
  • 2. eventually led the governments to reform, establishing maximum hours of work, beginning with the English Factory Act of 1802 and more particularly the Factory Act of 1850. However, capitals accepted it as rise in labor productivity, or in other words increase in per-hour productivity, compensated for fewer hours of work in a day or week. During the so-called “Progressive Era” (1890– 1913), several American states limited the work hours for women and children. The shorter- hours movement in the U.S. culminated in the passage of the Fair Labor Standards Act in 1938, establishing forty hours as a standard workweek as well as overtime pay premium to deter employers from exceeding it. Hence, as industrial capitalism matured over time, work hours became shorter, leaving more time for leisure, social interaction, and cultural pursuits. Workers earlier required fewer hours to spend at the workplace to earn the decent livelihood as their marginal value product increased. To a great extent, technological progress has determined the trade-off point between leisure and income or work. As income reaches the level required for a comfortable standard of living, workers put forward greater demands (in labor WorkingUSA: The Journal of Labor and Society · 1089-7011 · Volume 9 · June 2006 · pp. 199–213
  • 3. © 2006 The Author(s) Journal compilation © 2006 Immanuel Ness and Blackwell Publishing, Inc. negotiations) for more holidays, longer vacations, shorter work weeks, fewer hours per working day rather than demanding ever higher wage rates associated with longer working hours.1 Following productivity growth, output market demand was met with increased employment. If a firm wanted more hours of work from its existing workforce it had to pay a higher hourly rate than the normal wage in order to give an incentive to the individual worker to reduce the leisure time. With higher overtime payment, the individual is motivated to give up some of the leisure time because in this way she will reach a higher utility. However, after a critical point, the incentives do not work; relatively low income no longer deters absenteeism of the workers. Scandinavian countries provide the best examples of this. This went on from the days of Industrial Revolution in Britain until the end of the “golden age” of capitalism in the 1970s, or until the beginning of the Information Age of capitalism, so to say. The information and communications technology (ICT) was initially expected to take the work–leisure balance farther in favor of the
  • 4. latter, as the new technology appeared to have endogenized higher productivity. However, gen- erally the opposite seems to be happening. As the first shift (at the workplace) takes more time, the second shift (at home) becomes more hurried and ratio- nalized. The longer the workday at the office or plant, the more the workers feel pressed at home to hurry, to delegate, to delay, to forgo, to segment, to hyper- organize the precious remains of family time. That engages them in a third shift: noticing, understanding, and coping with the emotional consequences of the compressed second shift. On the whole, a social organization of time that served to synchronize the hours of work and leisure for much of the twentieth century is gradually disintegrating. The remarkable decline of average hours of work per worker over more than a century has reversed in the last two or three decades in all of the sectors of the economy that use computers in one form or the other. It is not yet clear what configuration of hours will ultimately emerge to replace the erstwhile standard workweek. In the U.S. in 1977, men worked an average of forty-seven hours and women an average of thirty-nine hours a week. By 2002, the numbers were at forty-nine hours a week for men and 43.5 hours a week for women (Bond 2002). Couples, it is found, are working longer and longer hours in the U.S., the
  • 5. heartland of the new technology. Combined work hours for dual-earner couples with children rose by ten hours from eighty-one hours a week in 1977 to ninety-one hours a week in 2002 (ibid.). Clearly, today’s working couples have less time for their lives off the job. Naturally, they ask: Live to work or work to live? Two explanations may be offered. First, on the supply side, individuals might have redefined the work–leisure trade-off point because the level of income that was earlier considered as “fair” is no longer so. It is no longer fair because either the social inequality has increased, thereby shifting the reference point of com- parison, or the same amount of work no longer, unlike in yesteryears, fetches the same amount of income. This of course goes against the basic understanding that wage is determined by productivity. Alternatively, in the era of shrinking social security, individuals are trying—with extra time of work—to earn a decent 200 WORKINGUSA: THE JOURNAL OF LABOR AND SOCIETY livelihood after their final withdrawal from the labor market. Hence, “work- leisure” has become a lifetime choice of an individual, and no longer remains a
  • 6. social agenda. In which case, however, the amount of work that had been adequate to fetch a fair superannuating seems to be no longer so even if labor productivity has gone up considerably. Second, on the demand-side, in response to increased productivity, employ- ers perhaps prefer longer hours of work by the existing workforce—those that are specially trained on-the-job—as opposed to keeping working hours intact and increasing employment. To them, additional employment implies additional costs of training for the new recruits and other transactions costs. This however inadequately explains the ten to twelve hours of daily work in the call centers, or in the data-entry jobs requiring average skills. Perhaps the lack of legislation or institutional measures of the type that protected the stipulated working hours in the shops and commercial establishments explains the phenomenon. Many scholars identify neoliberalism with casualization of the workforce. By overt as well as clandestine reforms in the existing labor laws, the workers have been stripped of job security, and even occupational status. Production as well as service organizations have been redesigning the occupations and designations that best suit the flexibilization program. This, in turn, takes away many stipu- lated rights designed for specific categories of workers. For
  • 7. example, the earlier “office clerk” is now designated as “junior management executive,” “supervisor” as “production executive,” “worker” as “knowledge technologist,” and so on, and eventually lose many of the rights the worker was entitled to so long as the worker was covered by the definition of “workman” under the Industrial Disputes Act in India, or similar other Acts elsewhere in the world. It is also important to recognize the changes in the interface between market and organization. Regulated markets were thought by the neoliberals to have encouraged the dominance of organization over market. In other words, as argued, the increase in monopoly or oligopoly during the “golden age of capi- talism” was an offshoot of markets regulated by various institutional rules in most of the countries. Deregulation has made the world flat, as the argument goes. However, the supremacy of the production or service organization over the state has been gaining more solid ground despite the theoretical hypocrisy of neoliberalism. The employers are now armed with renewed sovereign powers over their employees to deprive them of productivity gains. Our main inquiry is focused on the paradox: new innovations based on microchips have unleashed immense power for productivity growth yet the
  • 8. squeeze of leisure time, increased work hours especially of the knowledge workers and, more significantly, reduced pay are the dominant features of the economy cutting across developed and developing countries. It is argued, in this article, that (1) transition from “disembodied” to “embodied” technology, and (2) the changing quality of workers, together tend to increase the bargaining power of the knowledge workers. However, the reforms in the existing labor laws have engaged them in a work condition that is only comparable to that in the premodern industrial society. In Section 2, the 201BANERJEE: PRODUCTIVITY AND LEISURE distinguishing features of the skills that isolated the knowledge workers from the rest have been classified. The emerging relationships between the state and the knowledge workers are analyzed in Section 3. The paradox is probed in Section 4. This is followed by a few concluding remarks in Section 5. Skills That Rupture Solidarity There are certain distinguishing characteristics of the new technology. First, since 1965, the power of computers as measured by the number of transistors per microchip has doubled every 18 months—a stupendous increase
  • 9. in the process- ing power. By the same exponential formula, a laptop that cost US$3,000 in 1990 could cost US$6 today (Negroponte 2004, 6). But, one would not find any US$6 laptop in the market. The problem is that the hardware in the computer is nonfunctional without the “logic structure of functioning” ploughed by human “brains” into it. This is a rather radical departure from the logic of mechanics. The emerging Knowledge Economy (KE) based on new technology is characterized by the recognition of knowledge as a source of competitiveness, the increasing importance of science, research, technology, and innovation in knowledge creation, and the use of computers and the Internet to generate, share, and apply knowledge. In brief, KE refers to the use of knowledge to produce economic benefits. A knowledge-based economy relies primarily on the use of ideas rather than physical abilities and on the application of technology rather than the transformation of raw materials. A large part of the KE is known as the information technology (IT) industry that encompasses the creation, production, distribution, purchase, and sale of IT components, products, acces- sories, and packaged solutions in the areas of communication, memory, multi- media, networking, storage and computer hardware, software, systems, and
  • 10. peripherals complemented by a host of supporting and electronic services. This includes software services and products, and IT-enabled services (ITES). The latter, in turn, includes human resource-related services such as customer interaction, like call centers, financial processing and accounting, and data management. The use of IT assets in different sectors in the U.S., currently the most extensive IT user in the world, gives a fair idea of the KE—the economy within an economy (Table 1). Computers are, in fact, heavily concentrated in the services sector in the U.S., and hence the impact of IT on the economic performance is more visible in the latter than in other parts of the economy. The goods-producing sectors—agriculture, mining, manufacturing, and construction—are much less IT-intensive. Thus, a knowledge worker is anyone who works for a living at the tasks of developing or using knowledge—someone who primarily produces, distributes or manipulates information rather than engages in the manufacture of physical products or the delivery of tangible services. In other words, a knowledge worker might be someone who works at any of the tasks of planning, acquiring, search- ing, analyzing, organizing, storing, programming, distributing, marketing, or
  • 11. 202 WORKINGUSA: THE JOURNAL OF LABOR AND SOCIETY otherwise contributing to the transformation and commerce of information and those (often the same people) who work at using the knowledge so produced. Knowledge workers include those in the IT fields, such as programmers, systems analysts, technical writers, academic professionals, researchers, and so on. The term is also frequently used to include people outside of IT, such as lawyers, teachers, scientists of all kinds, and also students of all kinds. One approach is to define knowledge workers by their occupation. Knowl- edge workers can also be classified according to the industry they are employed in. For example, the software industry requires people having software skills such as programming, web development, coding, designing, etc. On the other hand, the skill profile requirement for the ITES industry is very different; employees require linguistic skills and appropriate domain/functional experience. The most striking growth, however, is that of “knowledge technologists”: computer technicians, data-entry operators, software designers, and analysts in
  • 12. clinical labs, manufacturing technologists, and paralegals (Drucker 2001). These people are as much manual workers as they are knowledge workers. In fact, they usually spend far more time working with their hands than with their brains. But their manual work is based on a substantial amount of theoretical knowledge, which can be acquired only through formal education, and not through an apprenticeship. They are not, as a rule, much better paid than traditional skilled workers are, but they see themselves as “professionals.” Just as unskilled manual workers in manufacturing were the dominant social and political force in the twentieth century, knowledge technologists are likely to become the dominant social—and perhaps also political—force over the next decades. As regards the gender distribution, the share of computing machine opera- tors among women IT-occupation workers is significantly higher than among male workers. The rapid growth of the ITES sector would see a rapid increase in the number of women computing machine operators—the ratio of males to females is 35:65 among the employees in India (Nasscom 2004a). This is perhaps Table 1. Information Technology as a Percentage of Stock of All Equipment and Software in Respective Sectors in the U.S., 2001 Sector %
  • 13. Legal services 37 Wholesale trade 31 Business services 30 Education 27 Printing and publishing 20 Finance, insurance, real estate 18 Instruments 19 Retail trade 12.5 Health 12 Manufacturing, agriculture, electricity, gas and power, transportation 1 to 8 Source: OECD 2004. 203BANERJEE: PRODUCTIVITY AND LEISURE not a chance happening of the supply and demand cross, but rather a outcome of a deliberate decision. The status of the knowledge workers, especially in the much- hyped upper ends of the IT job market, was brought to light during the IT bubble burst in Bangalore (India) in 2001–2002. The crash for the first time had turned the spotlight on labor relations and employment conditions as well as on more intricate aspects of the KE. The silicon-collared “professionals” did not even have the solace of a golden handshake like their blue-collared
  • 14. brethren. The “pink slip” phenomenon had rudely awakened them to the inhuman and ruthless management practices of capitalism, making them realize that they too are wage laborers. Some of them were forced to do hourly rated work depending on its availability, something worse than the condition of day laborers. Like construc- tion laborers, they got a job only when there was work. Job- hopping, a favorite pastime, was no longer the “in” thing. With every (forced) job switchover the wages decreased unlike before. Many workers worked in this stifling atmo- sphere, where every moment they were made to feel that they were no longer wanted. The much talked about employee stock options became a joke after the crash, when the shares were not worth the value of the paper they were printed on. Bargaining Power of Knowledge Workers Dwarfed Under the (Indian) Shops and Commercial Establishments Act of 1961— which covers IT establishments—the working hours are limited to nine per day and fifty-one per week. Overtime work up to 120 hours in a year is permissible, which is to be paid for at double the ordinary rates. No worker is to work for more than five hours in a day without a rest interval. The Act provides for one-and-a-half holidays with pay each week. According to
  • 15. Section 8 of the 1961 act, Where an employee works in any establishment for more than nine hours in any day or for more than forty eight hours in any week he shall in respect of such overtime work be entitled to wages at twice the rate of normal wages (Shops and Commerical Establishments Act, 1961). In 1998, the government of India constituted the Council on Trade and Industry to the prime minister (with the prime minister as its chairman). The council subsequently constituted six Special Subject Groups, one of which was the “Knowledge-based industries.”2 The recommendations (in April 2000) of the latter task force contained a great deal on fundamental reforms in the Shops and Commercial Establishments Act of 1961 and Rules 1963. The main targets of the task force were: (1) restrictions on working hours (Section 7 of the act); (2) restrictions on period of work (Sections 9 and 10); (3) extra wages for overtime (Section 8); and (4) provisions of earned leave and sick leave (Section 15). 204 WORKINGUSA: THE JOURNAL OF LABOR AND SOCIETY The argument of the task force against Section 8 of the 1961 act
  • 16. was: “In view of flexi-time the payment at double the wage rates is not only inappropriate but also wholly unreasonable. It is, therefore, essential that the rule be made not applicable to KBCs [Knowledge-based companies]” (Council on Trade and Industry Subject Group 2000). This initiative by the government of India unleashed the possibility of exploiting the employees beyond the hours of work defined by the 1961 act. It also allowed or gave “official” sanctions to bypass the obligatory payments for overtime work. Many of the Indian states subsequently amended their labor laws in that spirit. The Shops and Commercial Establishments Act became a passive instrument once the ITES in most of the states were granted the status of “public utility service” providers under the Industrial Disputes Act of 1947. In view of the understanding of 24/365 operations, various state governments have classified the ITES sector as “public utility service.” Most of the employees in ITES organizations have thus been pushed outside the purview of the regulating laws that are still applicable for the blue-collared workers. Under Section 13 of the West Bengal Shops and Commercial Establish- ments Act of 1963, for example, the ITES companies now have an option of giving compensatory day off to an employee if the quantum of
  • 17. work exceeds forty-eight hours a week. Given the round-the-clock nature of work (which, strictly speaking, is not true in India) that is part of the ITES industry, the government exempts these establishments from the following provisions of the act: (1) Closing an establishment and granting of a weekly holiday under Section 5 (1) of the act, which would enable the ITES companies to run their operations on all seven days of the week; (2) Opening and closing hours under Section 7 (1) of the act. This exemption would enable the ITES indus- try to run a three-shift operation; and, (3) working hours’ stipulation under Section 7 (2) of the act, which will enable “flexitime” operations for its employees. Moreover, many of the state governments in India have permitted self- certification, to the extent possible, of the IT industry in respect of the following Acts/Regulations: Payment of Wages Act, Minimum Wages Act, Contract Labor (regulation and abolition) Act, Workmen’s Compensation Act, Employ- ees State Insurance Act, and Payment of Gratuity Act, which so far protected workers against the whims of capitals. In other words, the IT firms have been allowed to remain outside the domain of regular and obligatory inspections by the government in matters relating to workers/employees.
  • 18. In almost all of the countries having codified labor laws, it is obligatory for the employers to pay overtime pay premium for each hour beyond the stipulated hours of work. Of course, in most of the countries, this does not apply to an employee employed in a bonafide executive, administrative, or professional capacity. Being designated exempt from overtime protection generally requires meeting three tests: (1) the amount of salary paid must meet minimum specified amounts; (2) the employee must be paid a predetermined and fixed salary, not an hourly wage that is subject to reductions because of variations in the quality or 205BANERJEE: PRODUCTIVITY AND LEISURE quantity of work performed; and, (3) the employee’s job duties must primarily involve managerial, administrative, or professional skills. Ironically, those days are over even though there is the euphoria “this is a wonderful time to be alive” (Gates 1995, 276). The U.S. Department of Labor adopted the regulatory changes in August 2004, which has almost taken away the rights of over six million workers to receive overtime pay for longer hours of work. The labor force is lured into the IT-job market often by such
  • 19. designations as “administrative,” “professional,” “junior management” or “executive.” However, they are the first and easiest to fleece; they are made ineligible for overtime pay no matter how low their salaries are. Millions of these workers in the U.S. will work longer hours at reduced pay. Changes in the primary duty test and the redefi- nition of “executive”—in the changed regulation—will allow employers to deny overtime pay to workers who do very little supervision and a great deal of manual and routine work. An employee who can only recommend—but not carry out—the “change of status” of, say, the two employees that she “supervises” will become an “executive” and be stripped of entitlements to overtime pay even if she manages nothing more substantial than a team or grouping of employees. Besides, it is estimated that, in the U.S., more than 900,000 employees without a graduate degree or even a college degree are designated as “profes- sional employees” and lose the right to overtime pay, even if their pay and status fall far below that of degreed employees. As many as 2.3 million team leaders redesignated as “administrative employees” with no supervisory authority will no longer be entitled to overtime pay even if they are line or production employees (Eisenbrey 2004). All in all, an estimated 1.4 million low-level,
  • 20. salaried supervisors will lose their overtime rights, along with 548,000 hourly supervisors, who could be switched to being paid on a salary basis and thus be denied overtime protection. The final rule codifies the worst of the federal case law, which holds that a low-paid Burger King assistant manager, for example, with no authority to hire or fire subordinates, who spends 90 percent of her time running the cash register and serving customers, and does not have discretionary powers, can still be classified as an exempt executive and be denied any pay for her overtime hours. Many of the occupational categories in the IT sector, in particular, would in this way be deprived of their existing rights although they might not be earning enough for their family’s adequate nutrition. It is important to recognize that lower salary groups are also increasingly being put outside the purview of overtime pay. Less-skilled employees are given the designation of “computer programmer” and are thus made gullible to their right to claim extra pay for extra work hours. In the U.S., there are about 288,700 programmers paid between US$455 a week and US$27.63 an hour who are affected by the changed rules. To note, a salary of US$455 per week means an annual salary of just US$23,660, which is about US$5,000 a year above the
  • 21. poverty level for a family of four in the U.S. Moreover, the exemption level is not indexed for inflation in the changed regulation; it will protect fewer and fewer workers over time. 206 WORKINGUSA: THE JOURNAL OF LABOR AND SOCIETY In India, unlike in the U.S., there is no official account available as to the occupational wage in the IT sector. However, a survey conducted among soft- ware professionals working in software firms and ITES in three representative cities, Bangalore, Delhi/Gurgaon, and Thiruvananthapuram (Abraham and Sharma 2005) reveals intriguing facts about the emerging labor market condi- tions such as high skill intensity, rapid skill obsolescence and continuous reskill- ing, and highly individualized and flexible nature of wage fixation. The wage/salary per annum of more than 40 percent of the total workers/ employees in different occupations in the IT and ITES is less than or equal to that of a lower division clerk in a public office, while the minimum educational qualification required for the latter is substantially lower than that of the former. Moreover, while the office assistants in the government offices continue to enjoy
  • 22. the benefits of overtime pay, their brethren in the IT sector look to the elusive “future.” Further, the per capita annual income of about 12 percent of the software engineers was almost equal to that of a “traditional” jute mill worker, while 2.3 percent of them on the upper end earned more than 1.7 times the income earned annually by a senior professor in a postgraduate university department. In other words, the variability of salary/wage at the same level of skill and in the same production process is also enormous. This personalized character of the labor market is bound to happen when institutions shy away from setting the rules of the game in the market or fail to provide a level playing field for all the players. What all these add up to is “longer hours and less pay” in those organi- zations that are exempt, by various ways, of many of the regulations that until recently gave protection to workers/employees against any unfair means of getting jobs done. Where has melted all those neoliberal sound bites of “open market”? In pure competition, the theory goes, wage is supposed to be equal to the marginal value product of labor (MVPL). The latter is the increase in the value of the firm’s output resulting from hiring one extra worker. In decid- ing about the level of employment, the firm compares the increase in costs
  • 23. from hiring one more worker with the increase in revenue, that is, it compares the wage with the MVPL. However, the basic assumption is that the firm can obtain as much labor as it wants at the current market wage (say, W0). So long as the MVPL exceeds W0, the firm should increase its employment level. If the MVPL is less than W0, the firm should reduce employment. Now, suppose the workers have acquired more skills, perhaps because of “learning by doing,” on-the-job training, or for some other reasons. So, there is a higher MVPL. Employment in the firm remaining the same, the MVPL curve will then move outward. So now the wage ought to be higher (say, W1), in which W0W1 is the economic rent (see Figure 1). The central issue is the conflict in sharing this economic rent. The employer complains that the trade union and the conventional labor laws deter higher profits and thereby capital accumulation. Because, the union demands—as they are empowered to do so by the existing laws—a fair proportion of the produc- tivity gains. So, as a countermeasure, employment is no longer construed as a 207BANERJEE: PRODUCTIVITY AND LEISURE person engaged for a specific duration of time as dictated by
  • 24. labor laws. Follow- ing a positive economic rent, work hours increase instead of an increase in the number of workers. The hourly economic rent thus flattens out, so the claims of the workers are invalidated. This is simple arithmetic; the explanation is rather complex. Anyway, no one asks: What is there for the employers’ consortium like Nasscom (National Association of Software and Service Companies)? Generally, the IT companies in India have a formal budget allocation for recruitment, which on an average is 7 percent of the total employee cost (Nasscom 2004a). However, a 7–14 percent reduction was reported in the allocated budget for recruitment, hiring, and orientation over the last couple of years. Further, 41 percent of the IT companies saw a significant workforce reduction (affecting 5 percent or more of the employees). In the ITES industry alone, 11.5 percent of the employees are affected (Nasscom 2004b). Neverthe- less, the rate of growth in the Indian IT industry continued to be positive (Nasscom 2004a). The conclusion is obvious: longer hours of work and less pay. Moreover, there is infringement upon the freedom of the employees to move out for better pay and/or service conditions. The current attrition rate in the industry is estimated at about 25–40 percent (Nasscom 2004a).
  • 25. Because of the costs associated with attrition levels, including investment in employee training etc., as alleged, a number of Indian IT firms have colluded against workers and started taking measures to limit attrition. Some of these measures include: (1) nonhiring of applicants who spent less than a year at their previous workplace or those who have changed three jobs in two years; (2) blacklisting of agencies who are actively involved in poaching candidates; and, (3) ensuring that candidates produce official release letters from the previous employer at the time of their appointment (ibid.). The knowledge workers are thus made captive, a parallel of which one may find, so to say, in the tea or rubber plantations in the nineteenth and early twentieth centuries. M V P L , w ag e W 0 E MVPL
  • 26. L* Employment E' W 1 L' MVPL' Figure 1. Wage, Productivity, and Employment. 208 WORKINGUSA: THE JOURNAL OF LABOR AND SOCIETY Decoding the Paradox Information and Communication Technology-based network of computers, especially the personal computers (PCs), which was initially in the 1960s meant for the defense establishments in the U.S. to integrate the university research departments into a network, became available for mass use and application in the early 1980s. The ICT productivity-led resurgence has close similarities with the general-purpose technology that emerged in the 1920s in the form of the dynamo and the electrification of the industrial economy that drastically increased labor productivity and reduced fixed capital costs. It is important to recognize that, in the 1960s, ICT was not hailed as revolution.
  • 27. Thomas Savery (Britain) invented the steam engine in 1698. However, it very slowly came into industrial use only half a century later and became almost synonymous with the English Industrial Revolution. The productivity crisis of capitalism in the 1970s similarly unlocked tremendous economic possibilities for the ICT technology of the previous decades. The emergence of the microprocessor and the diffusion of the PC, with their immediate possibility of distributed information storage and processing, set the stage for a radical change under a set of economic and social preconditions. Semiconductors are getting faster, computer memories are expanding, and ICT prices are falling. Data transmission costs have fallen dramatically and continue to fall, bandwidth is growing, and Internet hosts are expanding and multiplying. Cellular phone usage is growing worldwide, adding to the pace and capacity for change and innovation. The contribution of IT to aggregate productivity growth appeared to be disembodied initially.3 Rapid technological progress within the IT-producing industry itself raised the level of the general-purpose technology, and any firm could garner the benefits and make differences in competitiveness. Countries where the business sector has been quick in shifting resources toward the ICT industry and in adopting highly productive ICT equipment have
  • 28. been able to reap higher output and productivity growth rates (Cohen, Garibaldi, and Scarpetta 2004). In the latter half of the 1990s, things began to take new shapes. Productivity growth that embodies knowledge, know-how, and software assumed importance. Productivity improvement is no longer the property of just new capital invest- ment (cf. Solow 1960). And, market leadership rather depends to a great extent on developing distinguishing software and/or distinguishing computer programs. Growth in labor productivity is an aggregate outcome of three factors, namely, capital deepening, increase in labor quality, and increase in total factor productivity (TFP) (i.e., that part of the output growth that cannot be explained by increase in either capital or labor but by technological change). Jorgenson and Stiroh (2000) show that TFP in the Information Age, especially during the latter half of the 1990s in the U.S., had been quite high and comparable to that during 1959–1973. Capitalism somehow has recovered from the crisis that it faced in the 1970s. The repeat economic slowdown during 2000–2003, however, has challenged the emerging idea that the business cycle perhaps has come to an end, resulting 209BANERJEE: PRODUCTIVITY AND LEISURE
  • 29. from the spread of ICT. In the U.S., net stock (at current cost) of private fixed assets of the type “IT equipment and software”—in the nonresidential sector— increased at an annual average rate of 3.8 percent, from US$1,238 billion in 2000 to US$1,383 billion in 2003 (U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of Economic Analysis, Fixed Asset Table, 2005). Increase in “real” investments is particularly noteworthy in the context of rapidly falling ICT prices. The deep- ening of capital notwithstanding the economy experienced a slowdown. There are two explanations to the investment–output “mismatch.” First, the distinguishing characteristic of investments in the IT sector is that it cannot be equated with the earlier manufacturing investments. The unrelenting require- ments of an increasingly short product–replacement cycle in the IT sector have complicated the productivity scenario. A large part of the outlays on fixed technology costs is written off quickly. The high rate of technological progress resulted in a corresponding high rate of obsolescence of fixed capital. For instance, in the year 1995 before Windows 95 was introduced to the market by Microsoft, a 486 PC with 4–8 MB of random access memory, much lower
  • 30. capacity hard disk drive than that required by Windows 95 operating system (OS), and a much lower color resolution of the video monitor, were the optimal mix of capital equipment. Within a span of just ten years, a series of changes in the OS—useful or useless—has been rendering the computer hardware includ- ing the video monitor obsolescent in quick succession. It is not that all those changes led to higher and higher productivity. But because the earlier software product support services are withdrawn, the consumers are rather forced to go in for the newer configuration of the hardware. Those who expected miracles to happen out of this technology are at a loss. Although surging demands for new IT capital have boosted overall capital spending growth, the nation’s capital stock has not been growing at a similar rate. An estimate shows that 60 percent of annual corporate IT budgets go toward the replacement of outdated equipment and increasingly frequent product upgrades (Roach 1998). Besides, the underutilization of the capacity of IT capital stock in the economy has increased spectacularly.4 Second, in analyzing labor productivity, we have to go beyond the simple fact that the quality of labor (à la Gary Becker)—in the core IT sector—has vastly improved through formal education. The firm that tracks worker produc-
  • 31. tivity does so through fairly simple standards: hours per day or week on job, revenue or sales per employee, customer retention, and customer transactions per hour or day. Less popular, more industry-specific methods include measur- ing productivity by product cycles, net profit per employee, time from concept to working prototype, and factory output. The notion of comparing input with output is also pertinent for the software developer. The measure most com- monly used is: “size” as a ratio of “effort.” Size is normally measured using lines of code and effort per person days or months. Thus, productivity is equal to the lines of code per person months. The simplicity of the equation hides the problem of measuring effort. When a person states that they spent a day on the project it does not state whether this was 8, 12, or 16 hours. Many knowledge 210 WORKINGUSA: THE JOURNAL OF LABOR AND SOCIETY workers are now on the job much longer than the official data would suggest. The transition from industrial capitalism to “digital” capitalism, from the era of the dominating rule of the Factory Act to that of the Shops and Commercial Establishments Act, is also a passage from accounting for the work of the worker
  • 32. in terms of day(s) to hour(s)—the fearful broadening of the accountability of the knowledge workers. However, increasing the productivity of knowledge workers is going to be far more difficult to achieve than previous productivity breakthroughs for blue- collar and agricultural workers. Revolutions were all about sustained productiv- ity growth in the creation of tangible products by improving the efficiency of tangible production techniques. “Increase the speed of the conveyor belt in the assembly shop, the productivity of the workers would automatically increase” is the bygone era. By contrast, the supposed breakthroughs of the Information Age hinge more on an intangible knowledge-based product that is largely the result of an equally intangible human thought process (Roach 1998). The productivity growth in ICT manufacturing (say, computer hardware) is much faster than that in ICT using sectors (say, in computer software develop- ment) where labor input tends to be cerebral and much more difficult to replace with a machine. The Hicks–Marshall prototype of capital–labor substitution has thus become archaic in the KE. The limitations on boosting the cerebral effi- ciency of the knowledge worker have made it extremely difficult to raise their hourly productivity. At the point when ICT is introduced in an enterprise, one
  • 33. would find a leap forward in productivity, and then it flattens. The problem really is to sustain at least the initial rate of productivity increase. So, the rate of increase in output now depends on lengthening the working hours, given the number of employees. Thus, surfing the World Wide Web, performing after- hours banking, or hooking up to the office network from home, hotel, or airport waiting lounge have snatched larger time commitment from the knowledge workers. The latter has been legitimized by the reformed labor laws that bid farewell to the long-cherished democratic rights of the workers. Conclusion The specific nature of IT so far as the productivity part of it is considered has notionally strengthened the bargaining strength of the knowledge workers. But why the knowledge workers have not been able to resist the gradual erosion of the leisure time could be explained by (a) falling income per hour of work, and/or, (b) lack of State protection for the non-unionized workers. In the U.S., the hourly wage rate in the IT sector is found to be highest among “Computer systems analyst and scientist” in the year 2003. However, the hourly wage rate for “Physics teacher, postsecondary,” “Lawyer and Judge,” “Sociology teacher, postsecondary,” “Teacher, college and university,” or
  • 34. “History teacher, postsecondary” was much higher than the “computer systems analyst” (USDOL 2003). If the hourly wage rate was proportional to hourly value addition in all the economic activities, the “computer systems analyst,” in particular, and the IT 211BANERJEE: PRODUCTIVITY AND LEISURE occupations, in general, seem to be lagging behind many other knowledge workers as well as manufacturing occupations in terms of labor productivity. Based on the experience of the U.S. labor market, the disproportionality in the Indian labor market, especially in the IT sector, seems to have a converging trend and the wages afterwards would follow a downward curve as the supply situation of “specific skills” improve. Once the supply situation improves, which is very likely in the near future—which Nasscom predicts will take place in 2008—the wage differentials would automatically reduce and stabilize. Further, Indian vendors are likely to face increased competition from global vendors. Some of the advantages global companies have over Indian companies include: established customer relationships, robust training models, security systems for data privacy, business continuity plans, and deeper understanding of
  • 35. client businesses and business environments, especially in the U.K. and U.S. (Nasscom 2004a, 75). Besides, the influx of new vendors in the Indian IT sector and the subsequent increase in competition, along with the shrinkage in the dollar-output market may cause significant price undercutting, leading to increasing pressure on margins, and, in turn, on the greatest source of added value in the industry, that is, the knowledge workers. However, while many other knowledge (e.g., the teachers) as well as blue- collar workers would continue to enjoy many of the basic rights at work, the nonunionized IT workers including the knowledge technologists who see them- selves as “professionals” but not much better paid than traditional skilled workers, and the majority of whom are women, would remain deprived of collective representation. This whole situation reminds us of the plight of the factory workers in the early days of the English Industrial Revolution (Marx 1887, chap. 10, “The Working-Day”; Thompson 1963, chap. 6), and the his- torical path that the working class traversed over the last two centuries. Perhaps, there is no “End of History” (à la Francis Fukuyama 1992). Debdas Banerjee is Professor of Economics at the Institute of Development Studies Kolkata, West Bengal, India. He is the author of Globalization, Industrial
  • 36. Restructuring and Labour Standards: Where India Meets the Global, published by Sage Publications in 2005. Address correspondence to Dr. Debdas Banerjee, Calcutta University Alipore Campus, Block A, 5th Floor, 1 Reformatory Street, Kolkata 700027, INDIA. Facsimile: +91 33 2448-1364. E-mail: [email protected] idsk.org. Notes 1. There is the general agreement that the supply curve of labor by single individuals exhibits the backward- bending pattern, although economists disagree as to the shape of the aggregate supply of labor. The idea is that as the standard of living increases people find that unless they have the time to enjoy leisure activities, it is not worth their while to work harder in order to obtain the higher income required for more leisure. 2. Knowledge-based companies are typically engaged in the areas such as software development, consultancy, pharmaceuticals, financial services, engineering services, biotechnology, etc. 212 WORKINGUSA: THE JOURNAL OF LABOR AND SOCIETY 3. That is, acquisition of external technology in the form of patents, nonpatented inventions, licences, disclosure of know-how, trademarks, designs, patterns and computer and other scientific and technical services related to the implementation of technological product
  • 37. and process innovations, plus the acquisi- tion of packaged software. 4. Quite often very sophisticated high-performance PCs are used just for word processing or Internet surfing. References Abraham, V., and R. K. Sharma. 2005. New technology and the emerging labor market: A study of Indian IT industry. Indian Journal of Labor Economics 48 (4):789–802. Banerjee, D. 2005. Globalization, industrial restructuring and labor standards: Where India meets the global. New Delhi, London and Thousand Oaks, CA: Sage Publications. Bond, J. T. 2002. The national study of the changing workforce. With E. Galinsky, D. Prottas, and C. Thompson. Report No. 3, Families and Work Institute, New York. Cohen, D., P. Garibaldi, and S. Scarpetta. 2004. The ICT revolution: Productivity differences and the digital divide. New York: Oxford University Press. Drucker, P. 2001. The next society. The Economist, November 01. Eisenbrey, R. 2004. Longer hours, less pay. Briefing Paper No. 152, Economic Policy Institute, Washington, DC. Fukuyama, F. 1992. The end of history and the last man. New York: Free Press. Gates, B. 1995. The road ahead. New York: Viking. Government of India, Prime Minister’s Council on Trade and Industry. Subject Group on Knowledge-based
  • 38. Industries. 2000. “Recommendations of the Task Force on Knowledge-Based Industries.” Annexure V: Labor Legislation. April, New Delhi. http://indiaimage.nic.in/pmcouncils/reports/knowl/ (accessed July 27, 2005). Jorgenson, D. W., and K. J. Stiroh. 2000. Raising the speed limit: U.S. economic growth in the information age. Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 1:125–211. Marx, K. 1887. Capital. Vol. 1. Moscow, Russia: Foreign Languages Publishing House. National Association of Software and Service Companies (Nasscom). 2004a. Strategic review. New Delhi, India: Nasscom. Nasscom. 2004b. Nasscom Hewitt total rewards study. New Delhi, India: Nasscom. Negroponte, N. 2004. Hack out the useless extras. New Scientist, June 5. OECD. 2004. Understanding economic growth. Paris: OECD. Roach, S. S. 1998. No productivity boom for workers. Issues in Science and Technology 14 (4):49–56. Solow, R. M. 1960. Investment and technical progress. In Mathematical methods in social sciences, ed. K. J. Arrow, S. Karlin, and P. Suppes, Stanford: Stanford University Press. Thompson, E. P. 1963. The making of the English working class. Harmondsworth, England: Penguin Books. United States Department of Commerce. Bureau of Economic Analysis. 2005. Fixed Assets Table. Washington, DC: United States Department of Commerce, Bureau of Economic Analysis. http://www.bls.gov
  • 39. (accessed August 2005). United States Department of Labor (USDOL). Bureau of Labor Statistics. 2003. National Compensation Survey 2003. Washington, DC: United States Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics. http:// www.bls.gov (accessed August 2005). 213BANERJEE: PRODUCTIVITY AND LEISURE http://indiaimage.nic.in/pmcouncils/reports/knowl http://www.bls.gov http://www.bls.gov http://www.bls.gov Assignment Course / Subject: PUBLIC ADMINISTRATION Assignment Topic: Evaluation of Agency’s Human Resources Management for (ASPA) American Society of Public Administrators As a consultant, you need to develop an in-depth analysis and evaluation of the selected agency’s human resources management system and processes and then provide recommendations for improvement. Therefore, you will conduct interviews with agency representatives and research related academic sources and Websites. The analysis will be read by the VP of Accounts and Client Support as well as by the leaders of the agency for whom you are working. Write a five to six (5-6) page paper in which you: Analyze three to four (3-4) of the major components of the agency’s human resource system, processes, and performance evaluation plan for hiring and retaining a diversified workforce. (Title this section Human Resource Processes.)
  • 40. Analyze and describe the implications impacting the agency’s current employment trend, growth, and delivery of its products and services. (Title this section Implications of Human Resource Workforce.) Recommend two to three (2-3) managerial and professional skills and competencies required to improve the agency’s workforce by explaining each recommendation, providing reasons each recommendation would bring about improvement, providing two to three (2-3) ways the agency could implement programs in preparation for those skills not visible within the agency’s workforce as a method of promotion and advancement for current employees. (Title this section Succession Planning for Human Resource Management.) Describe the consultant position you are performing by (a) giving it a title; (b) explaining two to three (2-3) major specifications required of the job and how each will be measured in a performance evaluation; and by (c) explaining two to three (2-3) ways this position will be used within the various departments of the agency and for meeting the specific goals / objectives of the agency. (This job description will be provided to the Agency Director who has requested it. As a resource, you are to use the Dictionary of Occupational Titles, located at http://www.occupationalinfo.org/ and published by the U. S. Department of Labor located at www.usajobs.gov. (Title this section Job Analysis and Design.) Provide proof of one to two (1-2) interviews submitting the completed interview form with a list of questions for and responses from each interviewee. (Put this in the Appendix under Interview Forms.) Provide four to five (4-5) relevant and credible outside resources that support the content of this assignment. (Include no more than one (1) non-government Website.) Your assignment must follow these formatting requirements: Be typed, double spaced, using Times New Roman font (size 12), with one-inch margins on all sides; citations and references
  • 41. must follow APA format. Check with your professor for any additional instructions. Include a cover page containing the title of the assignment, the student’s name, the professor’s name, the course title, and the date. The sections must have appropriate titles. The cover page, reference page, and appendix pages are not included in the required assignment page length. The assignment must be submitted as a Microsoft Word document.