SlideShare a Scribd company logo
1 of 9
Download to read offline
A New Keynesian Model with Estimated Shadow Rate for Japan Economy
A New Keynesian Model with Estimated Shadow Rate for
Japan Economy
Rui WANG
Assistant Professor at Department of Economics, Kanto Gakuen University, 200 Fujiaku-cho, Ota, Gunma Prefecture,
373-0034, Japan
E-mail: kizuna.wr@gmail.com; Tel: +81-0276-32-7850
In this paper, we use Japanese government bond yield curve data to estimate the shadow rate
from a shadow rate term structure model. We firstly confirm the traceability of shadow rate as a
consistent and compatible measure of monetary policy which can be used to gauge the stance of
monetary policy implemented by Bank of Japan, then we introduce shadow rate in a standard
New Keynesian DSGE model and estimate the model using shadow rate estimated previously.
Finally, we check the empirical results from the New Keynesian model. Empirical results show a
good compatibility of the shadow rate used as a proxy of monetary policy in the estimation of
New Keynesian model, providing credible policy implications as the benchmark New Keynesian
model does in a standard context without the restriction of zero lower bound. Also, it has been
shown that the monetary easing policy conducted by Bank of Japan has significantly positive
effects on the improvement of the output gap and deflation. Using the shadow rate in the
estimation of DSGE models also avoids the technical difficulties incurred by the nonlinearity of
the zero lower bound.
Key Words: shadow rate, New Keynesian model, unconventional monetary policy, Bank of Japan, zero lower bound
JEL classification: E32, E44, E52
INTRODUCTION
When the short-term nominal interest rate is at or near zero,
central banks have to face the problems incurred by the
Zero Lower Bound (ZLB) because the ZLB invalidates the
implementation of conventional monetary policy, the
adjustment of short-term policy rate. Facing the constraint
of ZLB, central banks conduct unconventional monetary
policy to stabilize and stimulate the economy. This is what
Japan economy has experienced and Bank of Japan (BoJ)
has done since 1999 when the call rate decreased to a
very low level near zero. The Great Recession incurred by
the Global Financial Crisis 2007-2009 brought the same
problem to US, UK and Euro area. Besides the practical
policy issues faced by the monetary authorities in
advanced economies, the ZLB and the related
unconventional monetary policy also pose academic
issues and new challenges for macroeconomic research.
New Keynesian Dynamic Stochastic General Equilibrium
(NK-DSGE) model and Gaussian Affine Term Structure
(GATS) model are two main workhorses in modern
monetary macroeconomics and macro-finance. But when
the ZLB on the short-term nominal interest rate binds,
unfortunately, these models have deficient performance
and undesired economic implications, leading to
implausible and weird policy paradoxes and unsatisfied
fitness of data. As a standard methodology for monetary
policy analysis, a NK-DSGE model in the ZLB environment
predicts that positive temporary supply from supply side of
economy have contractionary effects and vice versa,
negative shocks from supply side of economy have
expansionary effects. Also, fiscal and forward guidance
multipliers can be implausibly larger than one. But
empirical works such as Wieland (2015) and GarΓ­n et al.
(2019) showed similar impulse responses of output to a
supply shock in both ZLB and non-ZLB environment. All
these conclusions from the standard NK-DSGE models
are inconsistent with economic intuition and empirical facts.
Besides the misleading policy implications, the ZLB also
Research Article
Vol. 5(1), pp. 106-114, June, 2019. Β© www.premierpublishers.org. ISSN: 3012-8103
World Journal of Economics and Finance
A New Keynesian Model with Estimated Shadow Rate for Japan Economy
Wang R. 107
brings many technical problems in DSGE methodology.
The explicit introduction of the ZLB constraint into DSGE
models accompanies with structural break or nonlinear
kink. Such kind of nonlinearity invalidates the linear
approximation and the Kalman filter. Some researchers
use global projection method and the particle filter to deal
with the nonlinearity in solution and estimation of DSGE
models, but these methods are technically difficult and
demand for numerous computations. As another main
methodology in macro-finance research, GATS models
which are widely used to fit the term structure of interest
rate can provide good description of the dynamics of short
interest rate in many macro-financial applications in the
non-ZLB environment, but in the ZLB environment, the
GATS models provide barely satisfactory fitness of data
and cannot accommodate the "sticky" property of short
interest rate. This "sticky" property means that the short-
term interest rates tend to keep approximately static
around the ZLB with lower volatilities for a long period of
time.
LITERATURE REVIEW
In recent research, the Shadow Rate Term Structure
(SRTS) model which was firstly proposed by Black (1995)
has become an alternative to overcome the poor
performance incurred by the ZLB in general GATS model.
Kim and Singleton (2012) and Bauer and Rudebusch
(2013) have used the shadow rate estimated from a SRTS
model to capture the behavior of interest rates and the
stance of unconventional monetary policy in the ZLB
environment. Krippner (2013) proposed a continuous-time
formulation of SRTS model, known as Krippner Affine
Gaussian model (K-AGM), where he added a call option
feature to derive the closed-form solution. Wu and Xia
(2016) took an analogous discrete-time approach which
can be directly applied to discrete-time yield curve data
without any numerical error associated with simulation
methods and numerical integration in other models. All of
these literatures advocate the effectiveness of the shadow
rate as a kind of measure for describing the monetary
policy stance.
Wu and Zhang (2016) established the equivalence
between shadow rate and unconventional monetary policy
in a standard NK-DSGE model. The equivalence between
shadow rate and unconventional monetary policy is
established on the empirical findings that have shown the
highly correlation between the quantity of government
bond purchase and the estimated shadow rate. The
shadow rate can take both positive and negative values
and show consistent response to monetary policy in both
non-ZLB and ZLB environment. Introducing the shadow
rate into a DSGE model can provide more insights for the
propagation and amplification mechanism of
unconventional monetary policy without introducing the
complications incurred by the ZLB constraint.
Methodology, Hypothesis and Main Conclusions
We take a combination of these two methods, using the
shadow rate estimated from a SRTS model as the data for
the estimation of a NK-DSGE model where the general
policy rate is replaced by the shadow rate. Then we use
the NK-DSGE model with shadow rate to do some
monetary policy analysis for Japan economy. This may be
a circuitous route, but the logic is valid and consistent from
the beginning to the end. Also, this approach salvages the
DSGE models from the nonlinearity incurred by the ZLB.
Standard procedures such as the linear approximation and
the Kalman filter can be used instead of complicated
nonlinear solution and estimation techniques. The main
hypothesis in this paper is that can we use the shadow rate
as a proxy of monetary policy in the monetary policy
analysis with DSGE models without considering the
technical difficulties of zero lower bound explicitly. Main
conclusion from this paper is that we can still use general
linear solution and estimation techniques of DSGE models
in the monetary policy analysis by introducing the concept
of shadow rate with a semi-structural approach proposed
by Wu and Zhang (2016). Estimation results from full-
sample and sub-sample shows that the structural
parameters are quite robust in the Bayesian estimation
with the estimated shadow rate. Also, historical
decomposition and impulse response also advocate the
effectiveness of the unconventional monetary policy
conducted by the BoJ.
The remaining of this paper is organized as follows.
Section 1 presents the estimation of shadow rate from a
SRTS model of Krippner (2013). We also check the
shadow rate's traceability as a summary for monetary
policy. In Section 2, we estimate a New Keynesian DSGE
model with shadow rate. Section 3 checks the empirical
results such as historical decomposition and impulse
response from the estimated DSGE model. Section 4
concludes this paper and gives the prospect for further
research.
1. Shadow Rate
Bauer and Rudebusch (2013) and Christensen and
Rudebusch (2014) pointed out that the estimated shadow
rates vary across different model specifications and
estimation methods. Kim and Singleton (2012) and Bauer
and Rudebusch (2013) use simulation-based estimation
method to estimate the shadow rate. Krippner (2013) and
Wu and Xia (2016) estimated an analogous SRTS model,
but with different time specifications, the former is in
continuous-time and the the latter is in discrete-time.
Krippner (2013) and Wu and Xia (2016) pose their
estimation codes on Internet. By replicating the estimation
of shadow rates for US, UK, Japan and EU, the results
don't show much difference in two methods. Ichiue and
Ueno (2013)'s estimation is based on the approximation of
bond prices by ignoring Jensen's inequality. Imakubo and
Nakajima (2015) also estimated a shadow rate model to
A New Keynesian Model with Estimated Shadow Rate for Japan Economy
World J. Econ. Fin. 108
extract inflation risk premium from nominal and real term
structures. By surveying related literature and replicating
the estimation results, we find that although the shadow
rates estimated from different model specifications and
estimation methods do have different values, they show
common trend and dynamics and lead to same economic
implications in the analysis of monetary policy, at least for
the major advanced economies, US, UK, Japan and Euro
area.
Also, most existing literatures advocate the potential
usefulness of shadow rate as a measure for the stance of
monetary policy. Bullard (2012), Krippner (2012),
Lombardi and Zhu (2014) and Wu and Xia (2016) all
support the view that the shadow rate is a powerful tool to
summarize useful information from yield curve data and
describe the conventional monetary policy stance in the
non-ZLB environment and unconventional monetary policy
stance in the ZLB environment in a consistent manner.
1.1. Estimation of Shadow Rate
Krippner (2012, 2013, 2014, 2015a, 2015b) provide a
detailed introduction of his methodology of term structure
modeling of shadow rate. For derivation of the model,
please refer to Krippner (2015b). We use yield curve data
of Japanese government bond to estimate the shadow rate.
See Table 1 for the summary statistics of yield curve data.
Table 1: Summary Statistics of Japan Yield Curve Data
Maturity 3M 6M 1Y 2Y 3Y 4Y
Mean 0.46 0.47 0.51 0.63 0.77 0.94
Med 0.12 0.13 0.15 0.25 0.40 0.57
Max 4.29 4.17 4.16 4.24 4.41 4.95
Min -0.42 -0.43 -0.37 -0.36 -0.36 -0.36
Std. Dev 0.85 0.83 0.85 0.90 0.97 1.06
Obs. 6360 6360 6360 6360 6360 6360
Maturity 5Y 7Y 10Y 15Y 20Y 30Y
Mean 1.10 1.40 1.81 2.13 2.53 2.70
Med 0.73 1.03 1.49 1.83 2.20 2.48
Max 5.25 5.71 5.64 6.16 6.44 6.24
Min -0.37 -0.39 -0.28 -0.13 0.03 0.05
Std. Dev 1.13 1.22 1.26 1.29 1.26 1.16
Obs. 6360 6360 6360 6360 6360 6360
The Figure 1 shows the plot of data from which we can find
that since 1999, the yield curve has shifted down to very
low level. The 3-months bond yield has begun to take
negative values since 2014M10. The yield curve data of
Japan is Japanese government bond data from 1992-Jul-
10 to 2016-Nov-24, daily frequency of 5-business days
week with 6360 observations, obtained from the
Bloomberg database. The maturity of yield curve is from 3-
months to 30-years and 3-months interest rate is adapted
to be the short interest rate, which is almost same as the
short policy rate of BoJ. Interest rates with other maturities
can be represented as a function of short interest rate and
forward rate in term structure models. The Figure 2 gives
the estimation result of shadow rate. The full series of daily
estimation for shadow rate from 1992-Jul-10 is available
upon request. We did the daily-frequency estimation of the
shadow rate and aggregated the daily-frequency data to
average monthly-frequency data. The gray shaded band
around the point estimate (red line in Figure 2) is the 95%
of the confidence interval. During non-ZLB period, the
shadow rate and call rate have almost same dynamics.
The shadow rate shows a good approximation to the call
rate. But during the ZLB period, the call rate is
approximately near to zero. We can't read too much
information about monetary policy from the call rate. But
the shadow rate has keeping decreasing. In next section,
we check the relation between the shadow rate and the
balance sheet of BoJ. Besides other unconventional
operations of the central bank, such as forward guidance
and direct facility lending, the enlargement of balance
sheet, widely known as quantitative easing (QE), is the
essence of unconventional monetary policy, especially for
the monetary policy of BoJ.
Figure 1: Yield Curve Data of Japanese Government Bond
Figure 2: Estimated Shadow Rate, Call Rate and 3-
months Bond Interest Rate
1.2. Empirical Evidence of Shadow Rate
We establish some empirical relations between the
shadow rate and the balance sheet.
A New Keynesian Model with Estimated Shadow Rate for Japan Economy
Wang R. 109
Figure 3: Balance Sheet of BoJ
BoJ is the first central bank which introduced
unconventional monetary policy among major advanced
economies. Table 2 summarizes the monetary policy
regimes of BoJ since 1999. The essence of the policy
programs conducted by BoJ is the large scale purchase of
Japanese government bond. From the Figure 3, we can
find since 2010M10, the balance sheet of BoJ has
increased aggressively. What is the relation between the
shadow rate and the size of balance sheet?
Table 2: Monetary Policy Regimes of BoJ
1999/2/2-2000/8/11: Zero Interest Rate Policy (pink
shaded area in Figure 4)
20013/19-2006/3/9: Quantitative Easing (yellow
shaded area in Figure 4)
2010/10/5-2013/3/20: Comprehensive Monetary
Easing (green shaded area in Figure 4)
20134/4-2016/1/29: Price Stability Target of 2% and
Quantitative and Qualitative Monetary Easing (blue
shaded area in Figure 4)
2016/2/16-2016/9/19: Price Stability Target of 2% and
Quantitative and Qualitative Monetary Easing with a
Negative Interest Rate
2016/9/21- Now: Price Stability Target of 2% and
Quantitative and Qualitative Monetary Easing with
Yield Curve Control
The Figure 4 shows the time series plot of shadow rate,
minus log of bond holdings and minus log of monetary
base.
Figure 4: Shadow Rate and Balance Sheet
The correlation between shadow rate and bond holdings is
-0.81 and the correlation between shadow rate and
monetary base is -0.82. The X-Y scatter plots also show
obviously negative correlation between the shadow rate
and the variables of balance sheet. Note that the shadow
rate can't be controlled directly by the central bank in the
ZLB environment. In the non-ZLB environment, the
shadow rate takes positive value which is same to the
general short-term policy rate. The short-term policy rate
can be controlled by the central bank through open market
operations. What the central bank can manipulate is its
balance sheet. The shadow rate just summarizes the
stance of policy. According to the empirical relation
between the shadow rate and the balance sheet, we can
map the manipulation of the balance sheet into the change
of the shadow rate.
2. Shadow Rate NK-DSGE Model
In this section, we first derive a standard NK-DSGE model,
then we incorporate the shadow rate into this standard
framework. We show that the shadow rate can be used as
an equivalence for QE so we can use the NK-DSGE model
with shadow rate to analyze the unconventional monetary
policy without considering the technical complexity
incurred by the ZLB.
2.1. Standard NK-DSGE Model
We assume that representative household maximizes the
discounted life-time utility 𝐸𝑑 βˆ‘ [
𝐢𝑑
1βˆ’πœŽ
1βˆ’πœŽ
βˆ’
χ𝐿 𝑑
1+πœ‚
1+πœ‚
]∞
𝑑=0 subject to
budget constraint 𝐢𝑑 +
𝐡𝑑
𝑃 𝑑
≀
𝑅 π‘‘βˆ’1
𝐡
π΅π‘‘βˆ’1
𝑃 𝑑
+ π‘Šπ‘‘ 𝐿 𝑑 + 𝑇𝑑 where 𝐢𝑑 ,
𝐿 𝑑, 𝐡𝑑, π‘Šπ‘‘, 𝑇𝑑, 𝑅𝑑
𝐡
represent consumption, labor, bond, real
wage, lump-sum transfer and private interest rate
respectively. 𝜎 is the inverse of inter-temporal substitution
of consumption and πœ‚ is the inverse of Frisch elasticity of
labor supply. The representative household discounts the
utility with objective discount factor 𝛽. Final-good firms
produce homogenous final-goods with CES-type
production function π‘Œπ‘‘ = [∫ π‘Œπ‘—,𝑑
Ξ΅βˆ’1
πœ€
𝑑𝑗
1
0
]
πœ€
πœ€βˆ’1
where π‘Œπ‘—,𝑑 is an
intermediate-good produced by intermediate-good firm. πœ€
is the elasticity of substitution among differentiated
intermediate-goods. Intermediate-good firms use Cobb-
Douglas production technology π‘Œπ‘—,𝑑 = 𝐴 𝑑 𝐿𝑗,𝑑
1βˆ’π›Ό
to produce
heterogenous intermediate-goods where 𝐴 𝑑 is total factor
productivity (TFP) that is common to all intermediate-good
firms. As a basic setup in standard NK-DSGE model, sticky
price is introduced by Calvo (1983)’s staggered price
setting mechanism. For the details of derivation, please
refer to Gali (2015), Walsh (2017) and Miao (2014). After
solving the optimization problems of each economic agent,
finally, the standard NK-DSGE model can be represented
by two equations, New Keynesian IS equation describing
the dynamics of output gap π‘₯𝑑 which can be derived from
the inter-temporal optimization of household.
A New Keynesian Model with Estimated Shadow Rate for Japan Economy
World J. Econ. Fin. 110
π‘₯𝑑 = 𝐸𝑑 π‘₯𝑑+1 βˆ’
1
𝜎
(π‘Ÿπ‘‘
𝐡
βˆ’ 𝐸𝑑 πœ‹ 𝑑+1 βˆ’ π‘Ÿπ‘‘
𝑁) (1)
and the New Keynesian Phillips Curve (NKPC) equation
describing the dynamics of inflation πœ‹ 𝑑 which can be
derived from the Calvo (1983)’s price setting mechanism.
πœ‹ 𝑑 = 𝛽𝐸𝑑 πœ‹ 𝑑+1 + πœ…π‘₯𝑑 (2)
Output gap π‘₯𝑑 is defined as the difference between output
under sticky price decentralized equilibrium and output
under flexible price decentralized equilibrium. ΞΊ =
(1βˆ’πœƒ)(1βˆ’π›½πœƒ)[πœ‚+𝛼+𝜎(1βˆ’π›Ό)]
πœƒ(1βˆ’π›Ό+πœ€π›Ό)
is a composite of deep structural
parameters. We introduce the economic explanations of
these deep structural parameters in next section. π‘Ÿπ‘‘
𝑁
is
Natural interest rate which is determined by exogenous
TFP process 𝐴 𝑑 in the standard context of New Keynesian
mode.
2.2. Shadow Rate in NK-DSGE Model
According to the empirical evidence of shadow rate
presented in Section 2, we introduce shadow rate into
standard NK-DSGE model. For general NK-DSGE model,
the economic agents face risk-free short rate π‘Ÿπ‘‘ and hold
risk-free bond. π‘Ÿπ‘‘ is generally recognized as the short
policy rate which can be controlled by the central bank. In
actual, the relevant interest rates affecting economic
agents’ decisions are private interest rates π‘Ÿπ‘‘
𝐡
through
which both conventional and unconventional monetary
policies transmit into the economy. Generally, the private
interest rates π‘Ÿπ‘‘
𝐡
can be represented as the sum of risk-
free short rate π‘Ÿπ‘‘ plus a time-varying risk premium π‘Ÿπ‘‘
𝑃
, π‘Ÿπ‘‘
𝐡
=
π‘Ÿπ‘‘ + π‘Ÿπ‘‘
𝑃
, where π‘Ÿπ‘‘ is assumed that can be adjusted by the
conventional monetary policy of the central bank.
Empirical works such as Gagnon et al. (2011),
Krishnamurthy and Vissing-Jorgensen (2012) and
Hamilton and Wu (2012) advocate that the large-scale
asset purchase by the central banks can reduce the risk
premium which means
βˆ‚rt
P
βˆ‚bt
G < 0 where 𝑏𝑑
𝐺
is the log of bond
holdings of the central bank. This is known as the risk
premium channel of QE.
Figure 5: Credit Spread and Balance Sheet
The Figure 5 shows the relation between credit spread and
the balance sheet. The credit spread used here is defined
as the difference between 10-years and 2-years Japanese
government bond returns. The correlation between credit
spread and log of bond holdings is -0.80 and the
correlation of credit spread and log of monetary base is -
0.81. According to the regression lines in Figure 5, we
assume that the response of risk premium π‘Ÿπ‘‘
𝑃
to bond
holdings 𝑏𝑑
𝐺
follows a simple linear form π‘Ÿπ‘‘
𝑃
= π‘Ÿ 𝑃
βˆ’ Ξ³(𝑏𝑑
𝐺
βˆ’
𝑏 𝐺) + Ξ΅ 𝑑
𝑃
where βˆ’Ξ³ =
πœ•π‘Ÿπ‘‘
𝑃
βˆ‚bt
G < 0 , π‘Ÿ 𝑃
is the constant
component of risk premium and πœ€π‘‘
𝑃
is the exogenous time-
varying component of risk premium which is interpreted as
the liquidity preference shock in Campbell et al. (2017). In
the non-ZLB environment, 𝑏𝑑
𝐺
= 𝑏 𝐺
, π‘Ÿπ‘‘
𝑃
= π‘Ÿ 𝑃
+ πœ€π‘‘
𝑃
such
that π‘Ÿπ‘‘
𝐡
= π‘Ÿπ‘‘ + π‘Ÿπ‘‘
𝑃
= π‘Ÿπ‘‘ + π‘Ÿ 𝑃
+ πœ€π‘‘
𝑃
which means that the
private interest rate is the short rate controlled by the
central bank plus risk premium. When π‘Ÿπ‘‘ is restricted by
the ZLB, approximately π‘Ÿπ‘‘ = 0 and π‘Ÿπ‘‘
𝐡
= π‘Ÿ 𝑃
βˆ’ 𝛾(𝑏𝑑
𝐺
βˆ’
𝑏 𝐺) + πœ€π‘‘
𝑃
through which the unconventional monetary
policy affects risk premium to reduce private interest rate
and stimulate the economy. According to the empirical
evidence of the shadow rate, we also assume that the
shadow rate has a same response to the log of bond
holdings in a linear form like 𝑠𝑑 = βˆ’Ξ³(𝑏𝑑
𝐺
βˆ’ 𝑏 𝐺), then π‘Ÿπ‘‘
𝐡
=
𝑠𝑑 + π‘Ÿ 𝑃
+ Ξ΅ 𝑑
𝑃
can capture the both conventional and
unconventional monetary policies.
In the non-ZLB environment, st = rt > 0 , bt
G
= bG
and
rt
B
= rt + rP
+ Ξ΅t
P
, the New Keynesian IS curve is
π‘₯𝑑 = 𝐸𝑑 π‘₯𝑑+1 βˆ’
1
Οƒ
(π‘Ÿπ‘‘
𝐡
βˆ’ 𝐸𝑑π 𝑑+1 βˆ’ π‘Ÿπ‘‘
𝑁)
= 𝐸𝑑 π‘₯𝑑+1 βˆ’
1
𝜎
(π‘Ÿπ‘‘ + π‘Ÿ 𝑃
+ πœ€π‘‘
𝑃
βˆ’ 𝐸𝑑 πœ‹ 𝑑+1 βˆ’ π‘Ÿπ‘‘
𝑁)
= 𝐸𝑑 π‘₯𝑑+1 βˆ’
1
𝜎
(π‘Ÿπ‘‘ βˆ’ 𝐸𝑑 πœ‹ 𝑑+1) + πœ€π‘‘
π‘₯
= 𝐸𝑑 π‘₯𝑑+1 βˆ’
1
𝜎
(𝑠𝑑 βˆ’ 𝐸𝑑 πœ‹ 𝑑+1) + πœ€π‘‘
π‘₯
(3)
where Ξ΅t
x
= βˆ’
1
Οƒ
(rP
+ Ξ΅t
P
βˆ’ rt
N) is a compound of
exogenous shocks. The risk premium shock π‘Ÿπ‘‘
𝑃
and rt
N
can't be identified separately, so we denote the compound
of these exogenous shocks as a demand shock Ξ΅t
x
.
In the ZLB environment, the New Keynesian IS curve is
π‘₯𝑑 = 𝐸𝑑 π‘₯𝑑+1 βˆ’
1
Οƒ
(π‘Ÿπ‘‘
𝐡
βˆ’ 𝐸𝑑π 𝑑+1 βˆ’ π‘Ÿπ‘‘
𝑁)
= 𝐸𝑑 π‘₯𝑑+1 βˆ’
1
Οƒ
(𝑠𝑑 + π‘Ÿ 𝑃
+ Ξ΅ 𝑑
𝑃
βˆ’ 𝐸𝑑π 𝑑+1 βˆ’ π‘Ÿπ‘‘
𝑁)
= 𝐸𝑑 π‘₯𝑑+1 βˆ’
1
Οƒ
(𝑠𝑑 βˆ’ 𝐸𝑑π 𝑑+1) + Ξ΅ 𝑑
π‘₯
(4)
which is same as its counterpart in the non-ZLB
environment. We can find that from equation (3) and (4),
New Keynesian IS curve with shadow rate has the same
specification in both ZLB environment and non-ZLB
environment.
Finally, we define a Taylor rule of shadow rate with interest
rate smoothing
A New Keynesian Model with Estimated Shadow Rate for Japan Economy
Wang R. 111
𝑠𝑑 = Ο† 𝑠 π‘ π‘‘βˆ’1 + (1 βˆ’ Ο† 𝑠)(Ο† π‘₯ π‘₯𝑑 + φππ 𝑑) + Ξ΅ 𝑑
𝑠
(5)
where Ξ΅t
s
is the monetary policy shock and φπ > 1
guarantees a unique, non-explosive equilibrium.
2.3. Estimation of NK-DSGE Model with Shadow Rate
From the analysis in Section 3.2, we can find the NK-
DSGE model with shadow rate has the same formulation
in both ZLB and non-ZLB environment given equation (3)
and equation (4). Because we have three observable
variables, output gap, inflation rate and shadow rate, we
add a shock term to the New Keynesian Phillips Curve
(equation (2)) to avoid the stochastic singularity in
estimation. According to Gali (2015, chapter 4), the shock
term can be explained as a cost-push shock which may
come from the exogenous variations in desired price
markups or exogenous variations in wage markups. The
main model is given in equation (6), (7), (8) and (9).
π‘₯𝑑 = 𝐸𝑑 π‘₯𝑑+1 βˆ’
1
Οƒ
(𝑠𝑑 βˆ’ 𝐸𝑑π 𝑑+1) + Ξ΅ 𝑑
π‘₯ (6)
Ο€ 𝑑 = β𝐸𝑑π 𝑑+1 + ΞΊπ‘₯𝑑 + Ξ΅ 𝑑
Ο€
(7)
𝑠𝑑 = Ο† 𝑠 π‘ π‘‘βˆ’1 + (1 βˆ’ Ο† 𝑠)(Ο† π‘₯ π‘₯𝑑 + φππ 𝑑) + Ξ΅ 𝑑
𝑠
(8)
All shocks follow first-order autoregressive processes
Ξ΅ 𝑑
shock
= ρshockΞ΅ π‘‘βˆ’1
shock
+ μ𝑑
shock
, shock ∈ (π‘₯, Ο€, 𝑠) (9)
where ΞΌt
shock
∼ N(0, Οƒshock
2
) is exogenous innovation term.
Figure 6: Data for Estimation
The data used for output gap π‘₯𝑑 in equation (6) which is
official estimate obtained from BoJ is from 1983Q1 to
2016Q3. The data series of inflation πœ‹ 𝑑 in equation (7) is
GDP deflator-based inflation rate from 1980Q3 to 2016Q3.
The data series of shadow rate in equation (8) is from
1999Q1 to 2016Q3. For non-ZLB period from 1983Q1 to
1998Q4, the shadow rate is replaced by the non-ZLB
constrained call rate to complete the full data series of
interest rate. Some structural parameters are
calibratedfootnote as 𝛼 = 0, 𝛽 = 0.9975, πœ€ = 6 and 𝜎 =
πœ‚ = 1. The elasticity of substitution πœ€ is calibrated to be 6
which means an average 20% markup charged by
intermediate-good firms at steady state. 𝜎 and πœ‚ are
calibrated at 1 because these parameters can't be
identified in the Bayesian estimation. 𝛼 = 0 means the
model economy has the constant scale to return. πœ… is a
composite of other structural parameters and we specify
its prior distribution as non-informative uniform prior
distribution U(0,1). The prior and posterior distributions of
parameters and standard deviations are given in Table 3.
We estimate the NK-DSGE in a DSGE-VAR style to
compare the theoretical impulse response from DSGE
model and corresponding empirical impulse response from
Bayesian VAR model. Please refer to Del Negro and
Shorfheide (2004), Adjemian et al. (2008), Del negro et al.
(2007) for the technical details of DSGE-VAR model. The
basic idea of the DSGE-VAR(πœ†) is to use the empirical
moments implied from a structural-from DSGE model as
the prior distribution for a Bayesian VAR model. When
choosing the prior distribution of a reduced-form Bayesian
VAR model, πœ† is the weight of this constraint of empirical
moments implied from the DSGE model. Following
Adjemian et al. (2008), we treat πœ† as a parameter which
can be jointly estimated from the Bayesian estimation of
other structural parameters and specify the prior
distribution of πœ† as non-informative uniform prior
distribution U(0,2). Also, we compare the impulse
response and calculate the historical decomposition to
check the contribution of the shadow rate monetary policy
shock to output gap and inflation.
The posterior distributions of structural parameters are
consistent with most of related literature on the NK-DSGE
estimation with non-ZLB constrained policy rate. For
example, given posterior mean of πœ… and other calibrated
structural parameters, we can calculate πœƒ as πœƒ =
1
2
(Θ βˆ’
√Θ2 βˆ’ 4) where Θ = 1 +
1
𝛽
+
πœ…
𝛽(πœ‚+𝜎)
. πœƒ represents
probability that an intermediate-good firm can't optimize its
price in the Calvo (1983)’s staggered price setting
framework. We find that πœƒ = 0.7313 means the duration of
price optimization is almost 11 months (3.7 quarters),
which is quite reasonable and consistent with most
empirical findings about the price adjustment. The
multivariate convergence diagnostic also shows good
convergence for all parameters. As a check of robustness,
we also give the estimation results from the 1999Q1-
2016Q3 sub-sample. The structural parameters still have
reasonable values and impulse response of monetary
policy also shows consistent dynamics of variables. But if
we use the ZLB-constrained call rate for sub-sample
estimation in the same period, we can't get any reasonable
results because it is almost impossible for a linear NK-
DSGE model, without using nonlinear techniques, to
capture the information of monetary policy from the ZLB-
constrained call rate with less dynamics.
3. Shadow Rate NK-DSGE Model in Monetary Policy
Analysis
By introducing the concept of shadow rate into a standard
NK-DSGE model and estimating it with the shadow rate,
the monetary policy analysis in the ZLB environment can
be done in a same way as the analysis in the non-ZLB
environment. We run some standard procedures of DSGE
methodology. Firstly, we show the historical
decomposition to check the contributions of each shock
3.1. Historical Decomposition
From the Figure 7, we can confirm the effects of monetary
policy represented by shadow rate, especially from 2014.
A New Keynesian Model with Estimated Shadow Rate for Japan Economy
World J. Econ. Fin. 112
Table 3: Bayesian Estimation of Structural Parameters
Prior Distribution
Posterior Distribution
(1980Q3-20016Q3 sample)
Posterior Distribution
(1991Q1-2016Q3 sample)
Parameters Mean St.Dev. Prior Mean St.Dev. 90% HPD Mean St.Dev. 90% HPD
πœ‘ πœ‹ 1.5 0.1 G 1.4895 0.1264 [1.2786,1.6923] 1.4679 0.1035 [1.2925, 1.6328]
πœ‘ π‘₯ 0.375 0.1 G 0.5896 0.1994 [0.2472,0.9084] 0.5839 0.1434 [0.3520, 0.8209]
πœ‘π‘  0.8 0.1 B 0.8088 0.0341 [0.7557,0.8669] 0.8506 0.0281 [0.8050, 0.8959]
𝜌 πœ‹ 0.8 0.1 B 0.4835 0.1393 [0.2694,0.7190] 0.4475 0.0906 [0.2967, 0.5921]
𝜌 π‘₯ 0.8 0.1 B 0.7713 0.0800 [0.6460,0.9060] 0.7949 0.0658 [0.6906, 0.9022]
πœŒπ‘  0.8 0.1 B 0.4868 0.0989 [0.3250,0.6457] 0.5421 0.0843 [0.4001, 0.6784
πœ‡ πœ‹
0.5 0.5 IG 0.2011 0.0353 [0.1475,0.2613] 0.2424 0.0367 [0.1730, 0.2912]
πœ‡ π‘₯
0.5 0.5 IG 0.2057 0.0318 [0.1491,0.2517] 0.2325 0.0432 [0.1749, 0.3130]
πœ‡ 𝑠
0.5 0.5 IG 0.1347 0.0160 [0.1096,0.1611] 0.1364 0.0168 [0.1088, 0.1629]
Parameters Prior Distribution Mean St.Dev. 90% HPD Mean St.Dev. 90% HPD
πœ… U(0,1) 0.1920 0.1741 [-0.0039,0.4726] 0.1058 0.0679 [0.0102, 0.2029]
πœ† U(0,2) 0.5174 0.1001 [0.3518, 0.6619] 1.3958 0.3007 [0.9527, 1.9328]
The positive contributions of the shadow rate monetary
policy shock (red area in Figure 7) from 2014 confirm the
effects of Quantitative Qualitative Monetary Easing (QQE)
of BoJ.
Figure 7: Historical Decomposition of Inflation
Figure 8: Historical Decomposition of Output Gap
Figure 8 shows the historical decompositions of inflation.
The most of fluctuations of inflation come from the supply
shock, demand shock and (shadow rate) monetary policy
shock. Also, (shadow rate) monetary policy shock has
positive contribution to positive inflation since 2014 (red
area in Figure 8). We can conclude from the historical
decompositions of output gap and inflation, the
enlargement of balance sheet of BoJ does have its effect
to improve the output gap and deflation.
3.2. Impulse Response Function
Bayesian impulse response functions (IRFs) are
calculated based on the posterior distributions of structural
parameters and exogenous shock standard deviations.
The gray shaded area represents the 90% Highest
Posterior Density Interval (HPDI) of posterior impulse
response calculated from DSGE model. The thick black
line is the medium of posterior impulse response of DSGE
model. The corresponding impulse response calculated
from Bayesian VAR is also plotted in dashed lines with
HPDI (90%) and the medium of impulse response inside
the two dashed lines. We can find the posterior impulse
response from DSGE model and VAR model has the
almost same dynamics, similar range and direction,
especially for inflation and (shadow) interest rate. Note that
even the shadow rate can take negative values, the
change of shadow rate, a rise or a reduction, still has the
same effect as the positive policy rate has in the non-ZLB
environment. The shadow rate NK-DSGE model shows
consistent IRFs no matter the policy rate is restricted by
the ZLB or not, both models show the output gap improves
due to the expansionary monetary policy shock.
Figure 9: IRF of negative (shadow rate) monetary policy
shock πœ€π‘‘
𝑠
Figure 10 shows the dynamic response of demand shock
πœ€π‘‘
π‘₯
. A positive demand shock can improve the output gap.
At the same time, monetary policy rule responses to the
corresponding increasing of inflation and output gap with
the increasing of (shadow) interest rate.
Figure 10: IRF of demand shock πœ€π‘‘
π‘₯
A New Keynesian Model with Estimated Shadow Rate for Japan Economy
Wang R. 113
Figure 11 gives the supply shock (cost-push shock) πœ€π‘‘
πœ‹
which can trigger the increasing of inflation. Also, the
(shadow) interest rate responses to the increasing of
inflation, which is totally same compared to the standard
context of NK-DSGE model.
Figure 11: IRF of supply shock πœ€π‘‘
πœ‹
We find that all these empirical results are same to those
in the standard NK-DSGE models although here we used
the shadow rate to estimate the model.
DISCUSSIONS
In this paper, we estimated the shadow rate of Japan
economy from a shadow rate term structure model. We
adopt the shadow rate as a measure of monetary policy of
BoJ because since 1999Q1, the general policy rate of BoJ,
call rate, has kept been near zero and already lost its
function as an operating target for the conduct of monetary
policy. The concept of shadow rate is not new and for a
long time, it is not widely used in macroeconomics. Since
the ZLB has become a common issue for monetary
authorities in the advanced economies, using the shadow
rate to observe and analyze the monetary policy has been
applied in many empirical works. We also confirmed that
the shadow rate does have credible traceability of the
BoJ's policy in the ZLB environment, providing us a new
perspective to check the unconventional monetary policy
of BoJ. Most of existing literatures use the shadow rate in
reduced-form time series econometric models such as
FAVAR or TVP-VAR to find the empirical evidences of
unconventional monetary policy, but these models are not
structural. The introduction of the shadow rate into the
DSGE framework is a new attempt. Using the shadow rate
does relieve us from the technical difficulties incurred by
the ZLB, but whether this method is robust or not is still
unclear. As far as we know, there doesn't exist other
similar works that use the shadow rate in the estimation of
DSGE model. However, the historical decomposition of
output gap and inflation advocates the effectiveness of the
monetary easing conducted by BoJ. The transmission
channels of the monetary easing policy which are
assumed in this paper are based on the empirical findings
and these empirical evidences have been mapped into the
model. Then we find that the impulse response functions
of shadow rate NK-DSGE model are similar to the
benchmark NK-DSGE model. The mechanism of the
general policy rate and shadow rate is same as the
standard NK-DSGE framework.
Note that there may exist one defect in the estimation of
DSGE models with shadow rate. It is that the shadow rate
is not endogenously derived from a structural model, but
exogenously estimated by a statistical model. SRTS model
is a factor model and the factors are used to fit and
describe the yield curve in a ZLB environment. But the
factors have less economic interpretation. Krippner (2015)
gives a structural interpretation of these factors in a linear
economy framework, but this framework is highly stylized
and has less dynamics than DSGE models. The estimation
of the shadow rate by SRTS model needs nonlinear
numerical calculations, this makes the endogenous
determination of the shadow rate in a structural DSGE
framework very difficult.
For further research, we want to introduce the shadow rate
to a Smets and Wouters (2003, 2007) type middle-scale
DSGE model, which is the prototype of the DSGE models
used in major central banks. Also, we shouldn't forget that
the shadow rate only exists as an economic concept and
the central bank can't control the shadow rate as an
operating target, but we can use the information from it as
a guidance for monetary policy operation.
REFERENCES
Adjemian, S., Darracq Paries, M., & Moyen, S.
(2008). Towards a monetary policy evaluation
framework (No. 942). European Central Bank.
Bauer, M. D., & Rudebusch, G. D. (2013). The signaling
channel for Federal Reserve bond
purchases. International Journal of Central Banking,
forthcoming.
Black, F. (1995). Interest rates as options. the Journal of
Finance, 50(5), 1371-1376.
Bullard, J. (2012). Shadow interest rates and the stance of
US monetary policy (No. 206). Federal Reserve Bank
of St. Louis.
Campbell, J. R., Fisher, J. D., Justiniano, A., & Melosi, L.
(2017). Forward guidance and macroeconomic
outcomes since the financial crisis. NBER
Macroeconomics Annual, 31(1), 283-357.
Christensen, J. H., & Rudebusch, G. D. (2014). Estimating
shadow-rate term structure models with near-zero
yields. Journal of Financial Econometrics, 13(2), 226-
259.
Del Negro, M., & Schorfheide, F. (2004). Priors from
general equilibrium models for VARs. International
Economic Review, 45(2), 643-673.
Del Negro, M., Schorfheide, F., Smets, F., & Wouters, R.
(2007). On the fit of new Keynesian models. Journal of
Business & Economic Statistics, 25(2), 123-143.
Gagnon, J., Raskin, M., Remache, J., & Sack, B. (2011).
The financial market effects of the Federal Reserve’s
large-scale asset purchases. international Journal of
central Banking, 7(1), 3-43.
GalΓ­, J. (2015). Monetary policy, inflation, and the business
cycle: an introduction to the new Keynesian framework
and its applications. Princeton University Press.
A New Keynesian Model with Estimated Shadow Rate for Japan Economy
World J. Econ. Fin. 114
GarΓ­n, J., Lester, R., & Sims, E. (2019). Are supply shocks
contractionary at the ZLB? Evidence from utilization-
adjusted TFP data. Review of Economics and
Statistics, 101(1), 160-175.
Hamilton, J. D., & Wu, J. C. (2012). The effectiveness of
alternative monetary policy tools in a zero lower bound
environment. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 44,
3-46.
Ichiue, H., & Ueno, Y. (2013). Estimating term premia at
the zero bound: An analysis of Japanese, US, and UK
yields (No. 13-E-8). Bank of Japan.
Imakubo, K., & Nakajima, J. (2015). Estimating inflation
risk premia from nominal and real yield curves using a
shadow-rate model (No. 15-E-1). Bank of Japan.
Kim, D. H., & Singleton, K. J. (2012). Term structure
models and the zero bound: an empirical investigation
of Japanese yields. Journal of Econometrics, 170(1),
32-49.
Krippner, L. (2012). Modifying Gaussian term structure
models when interest rates are near the zero lower
bound. Reserve Bank of New Zealand Discussion
Paper, (2012/02).
Krippner, L. (2013). Measuring the stance of monetary
policy in zero lower bound environments. Economics
Letters, 118(1), 135-138.
Krippner, L. (2014). Measuring the stance of monetary
policy in conventional and unconventional
environments. Centre for Applied Macroeconomic
Analysis, Crawford School of Public Policy, The
Australian National University.
Krippner, L. (2015a). A comment on Wu and Xia (2015),
and the case for two-factor Shadow Short Rates.
Centre for Applied Macroeconomic Analysis, Crawford
School of Public Policy, The Australian National
University.
Krippner, L. (2015b). Zero lower bound term structure
modeling: A practitioner’s guide. Springer.
Krishnamurthy, A., & Vissing-Jorgensen, A. (2011). The
effects of quantitative easing on interest rates: channels
and implications for policy (No. w17555). National
Bureau of Economic Research.
Lombardi, M., & Zhu, F. (2014). A shadow policy rate to
calibrate US monetary policy at the zero lower
bound (No. 452). Bank for International Settlements.
Miao, J. (2014). Economic dynamics in discrete time. MIT
press.
Smets, F., & Wouters, R. (2003). An estimated dynamic
stochastic general equilibrium model of the euro
area. Journal of the European economic
association, 1(5), 1123-1175.
Smets, F., & Wouters, R. (2007). Shocks and frictions in
US business cycles: A Bayesian DSGE
approach. American economic review, 97(3), 586-606.
Walsh, C. E. (2017). Monetary theory and policy. MIT
press.
Wieland, J. F. (2015). Are negative supply shocks
expansionary at the zero lower bound? Working Paper,
University of California, San Diego.
Wu, J. C., & Xia, F. D. (2016). Measuring the
macroeconomic impact of monetary policy at the zero
lower bound. Journal of Money, Credit and
Banking, 48(2-3), 253-291.
Wu, J. C., & Zhang, J. (2016). A shadow rate New
Keynesian model (No. w22856). National Bureau of
Economic Research
Accepted 28 March 2019
Citation: Wang R (2019). A New Keynesian Model with
Estimated Shadow Rate for Japan Economy. World
Journal of Economics and Finance, 5(1): 106-114.
Copyright: Β© 2019 Wang R. This is an open-access article
distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons
Attribution License, which permits unrestricted use,
distribution, and reproduction in any medium, provided the
original author and source are cited.

More Related Content

Similar to A New Keynesian Model with Estimated Shadow Rate for Japan Economy

Combining Economic Fundamentals to Predict Exchange Rates
Combining Economic Fundamentals to Predict Exchange RatesCombining Economic Fundamentals to Predict Exchange Rates
Combining Economic Fundamentals to Predict Exchange Rates
Brant Munro
Β 
Fiscal Policy And Trade Openness On Unemployment Essay
Fiscal Policy And Trade Openness On Unemployment EssayFiscal Policy And Trade Openness On Unemployment Essay
Fiscal Policy And Trade Openness On Unemployment Essay
Rachel Phillips
Β 
Dissertation final1
Dissertation final1Dissertation final1
Dissertation final1
Arinze Nwoye
Β 
Default-Forecasting Project
Default-Forecasting ProjectDefault-Forecasting Project
Default-Forecasting Project
Joey Nichols
Β 

Similar to A New Keynesian Model with Estimated Shadow Rate for Japan Economy (20)

A dynamic Nelson-Siegel model with forward-looking indicators for the yield c...
A dynamic Nelson-Siegel model with forward-looking indicators for the yield c...A dynamic Nelson-Siegel model with forward-looking indicators for the yield c...
A dynamic Nelson-Siegel model with forward-looking indicators for the yield c...
Β 
Multifactorial Heath-Jarrow-Morton model using principal component analysis
Multifactorial Heath-Jarrow-Morton model using principal component analysisMultifactorial Heath-Jarrow-Morton model using principal component analysis
Multifactorial Heath-Jarrow-Morton model using principal component analysis
Β 
Empirical Macroeconomic Model of the Finnish Economy (EMMA)
Empirical Macroeconomic Model of the Finnish Economy (EMMA)Empirical Macroeconomic Model of the Finnish Economy (EMMA)
Empirical Macroeconomic Model of the Finnish Economy (EMMA)
Β 
CASE Network Studies and Analyses 246 - Monetary Policy in Transition: Struct...
CASE Network Studies and Analyses 246 - Monetary Policy in Transition: Struct...CASE Network Studies and Analyses 246 - Monetary Policy in Transition: Struct...
CASE Network Studies and Analyses 246 - Monetary Policy in Transition: Struct...
Β 
Choudhri et-al-2015-working-paper-1
Choudhri et-al-2015-working-paper-1Choudhri et-al-2015-working-paper-1
Choudhri et-al-2015-working-paper-1
Β 
Combining Economic Fundamentals to Predict Exchange Rates
Combining Economic Fundamentals to Predict Exchange RatesCombining Economic Fundamentals to Predict Exchange Rates
Combining Economic Fundamentals to Predict Exchange Rates
Β 
QUALITY ASSURANCE FOR ECONOMY CLASSIFICATION BASED ON DATA MINING TECHNIQUES
QUALITY ASSURANCE FOR ECONOMY CLASSIFICATION BASED ON DATA MINING TECHNIQUESQUALITY ASSURANCE FOR ECONOMY CLASSIFICATION BASED ON DATA MINING TECHNIQUES
QUALITY ASSURANCE FOR ECONOMY CLASSIFICATION BASED ON DATA MINING TECHNIQUES
Β 
Naszodi a
Naszodi aNaszodi a
Naszodi a
Β 
Application of consistency and efficiency test for forecasts
Application of consistency and efficiency test for forecastsApplication of consistency and efficiency test for forecasts
Application of consistency and efficiency test for forecasts
Β 
Fiscal Policy And Trade Openness On Unemployment Essay
Fiscal Policy And Trade Openness On Unemployment EssayFiscal Policy And Trade Openness On Unemployment Essay
Fiscal Policy And Trade Openness On Unemployment Essay
Β 
Dissertation final1
Dissertation final1Dissertation final1
Dissertation final1
Β 
GDP Modeling Using Autoregressive Integrated Moving Average (ARIMA): A Case f...
GDP Modeling Using Autoregressive Integrated Moving Average (ARIMA): A Case f...GDP Modeling Using Autoregressive Integrated Moving Average (ARIMA): A Case f...
GDP Modeling Using Autoregressive Integrated Moving Average (ARIMA): A Case f...
Β 
International Finance
International FinanceInternational Finance
International Finance
Β 
220 F
220 F220 F
220 F
Β 
C0331021038
C0331021038C0331021038
C0331021038
Β 
Quantifying the Uncertainty of Long-Term Economic Projections
Quantifying the Uncertainty of Long-Term Economic ProjectionsQuantifying the Uncertainty of Long-Term Economic Projections
Quantifying the Uncertainty of Long-Term Economic Projections
Β 
tkacik_final
tkacik_finaltkacik_final
tkacik_final
Β 
Nonlinear Extension of Asymmetric Garch Model within Neural Network Framework
Nonlinear Extension of Asymmetric Garch Model within Neural Network Framework Nonlinear Extension of Asymmetric Garch Model within Neural Network Framework
Nonlinear Extension of Asymmetric Garch Model within Neural Network Framework
Β 
NONLINEAR EXTENSION OF ASYMMETRIC GARCH MODEL WITHIN NEURAL NETWORK FRAMEWORK
NONLINEAR EXTENSION OF ASYMMETRIC GARCH MODEL WITHIN NEURAL NETWORK FRAMEWORKNONLINEAR EXTENSION OF ASYMMETRIC GARCH MODEL WITHIN NEURAL NETWORK FRAMEWORK
NONLINEAR EXTENSION OF ASYMMETRIC GARCH MODEL WITHIN NEURAL NETWORK FRAMEWORK
Β 
Default-Forecasting Project
Default-Forecasting ProjectDefault-Forecasting Project
Default-Forecasting Project
Β 

More from Premier Publishers

Enhancing Social Capital During the Pandemic: A Case of the Rural Women in Bu...
Enhancing Social Capital During the Pandemic: A Case of the Rural Women in Bu...Enhancing Social Capital During the Pandemic: A Case of the Rural Women in Bu...
Enhancing Social Capital During the Pandemic: A Case of the Rural Women in Bu...
Premier Publishers
Β 
Impact of Provision of Litigation Supports through Forensic Investigations on...
Impact of Provision of Litigation Supports through Forensic Investigations on...Impact of Provision of Litigation Supports through Forensic Investigations on...
Impact of Provision of Litigation Supports through Forensic Investigations on...
Premier Publishers
Β 
Urban Liveability in the Context of Sustainable Development: A Perspective fr...
Urban Liveability in the Context of Sustainable Development: A Perspective fr...Urban Liveability in the Context of Sustainable Development: A Perspective fr...
Urban Liveability in the Context of Sustainable Development: A Perspective fr...
Premier Publishers
Β 
Multivariate Analysis of Tea (Camellia sinensis (L.) O. Kuntze) Clones on Mor...
Multivariate Analysis of Tea (Camellia sinensis (L.) O. Kuntze) Clones on Mor...Multivariate Analysis of Tea (Camellia sinensis (L.) O. Kuntze) Clones on Mor...
Multivariate Analysis of Tea (Camellia sinensis (L.) O. Kuntze) Clones on Mor...
Premier Publishers
Β 
Causes, Consequences and Remedies of Juvenile Delinquency in the Context of S...
Causes, Consequences and Remedies of Juvenile Delinquency in the Context of S...Causes, Consequences and Remedies of Juvenile Delinquency in the Context of S...
Causes, Consequences and Remedies of Juvenile Delinquency in the Context of S...
Premier Publishers
Β 
The Knowledge of and Attitude to and Beliefs about Causes and Treatments of M...
The Knowledge of and Attitude to and Beliefs about Causes and Treatments of M...The Knowledge of and Attitude to and Beliefs about Causes and Treatments of M...
The Knowledge of and Attitude to and Beliefs about Causes and Treatments of M...
Premier Publishers
Β 
Effect of Phosphorus and Zinc on the Growth, Nodulation and Yield of Soybean ...
Effect of Phosphorus and Zinc on the Growth, Nodulation and Yield of Soybean ...Effect of Phosphorus and Zinc on the Growth, Nodulation and Yield of Soybean ...
Effect of Phosphorus and Zinc on the Growth, Nodulation and Yield of Soybean ...
Premier Publishers
Β 
Performance evaluation of upland rice (Oryza sativa L.) and variability study...
Performance evaluation of upland rice (Oryza sativa L.) and variability study...Performance evaluation of upland rice (Oryza sativa L.) and variability study...
Performance evaluation of upland rice (Oryza sativa L.) and variability study...
Premier Publishers
Β 
Harnessing the Power of Agricultural Waste: A Study of Sabo Market, Ikorodu, ...
Harnessing the Power of Agricultural Waste: A Study of Sabo Market, Ikorodu, ...Harnessing the Power of Agricultural Waste: A Study of Sabo Market, Ikorodu, ...
Harnessing the Power of Agricultural Waste: A Study of Sabo Market, Ikorodu, ...
Premier Publishers
Β 
Influence of Conferences and Job Rotation on Job Productivity of Library Staf...
Influence of Conferences and Job Rotation on Job Productivity of Library Staf...Influence of Conferences and Job Rotation on Job Productivity of Library Staf...
Influence of Conferences and Job Rotation on Job Productivity of Library Staf...
Premier Publishers
Β 

More from Premier Publishers (20)

Evaluation of Agro-morphological Performances of Hybrid Varieties of Chili Pe...
Evaluation of Agro-morphological Performances of Hybrid Varieties of Chili Pe...Evaluation of Agro-morphological Performances of Hybrid Varieties of Chili Pe...
Evaluation of Agro-morphological Performances of Hybrid Varieties of Chili Pe...
Β 
An Empirical Approach for the Variation in Capital Market Price Changes
An Empirical Approach for the Variation in Capital Market Price Changes An Empirical Approach for the Variation in Capital Market Price Changes
An Empirical Approach for the Variation in Capital Market Price Changes
Β 
Influence of Nitrogen and Spacing on Growth and Yield of Chia (Salvia hispani...
Influence of Nitrogen and Spacing on Growth and Yield of Chia (Salvia hispani...Influence of Nitrogen and Spacing on Growth and Yield of Chia (Salvia hispani...
Influence of Nitrogen and Spacing on Growth and Yield of Chia (Salvia hispani...
Β 
Enhancing Social Capital During the Pandemic: A Case of the Rural Women in Bu...
Enhancing Social Capital During the Pandemic: A Case of the Rural Women in Bu...Enhancing Social Capital During the Pandemic: A Case of the Rural Women in Bu...
Enhancing Social Capital During the Pandemic: A Case of the Rural Women in Bu...
Β 
Impact of Provision of Litigation Supports through Forensic Investigations on...
Impact of Provision of Litigation Supports through Forensic Investigations on...Impact of Provision of Litigation Supports through Forensic Investigations on...
Impact of Provision of Litigation Supports through Forensic Investigations on...
Β 
Improving the Efficiency of Ratio Estimators by Calibration Weightings
Improving the Efficiency of Ratio Estimators by Calibration WeightingsImproving the Efficiency of Ratio Estimators by Calibration Weightings
Improving the Efficiency of Ratio Estimators by Calibration Weightings
Β 
Urban Liveability in the Context of Sustainable Development: A Perspective fr...
Urban Liveability in the Context of Sustainable Development: A Perspective fr...Urban Liveability in the Context of Sustainable Development: A Perspective fr...
Urban Liveability in the Context of Sustainable Development: A Perspective fr...
Β 
Transcript Level of Genes Involved in β€œRebaudioside A” Biosynthesis Pathway u...
Transcript Level of Genes Involved in β€œRebaudioside A” Biosynthesis Pathway u...Transcript Level of Genes Involved in β€œRebaudioside A” Biosynthesis Pathway u...
Transcript Level of Genes Involved in β€œRebaudioside A” Biosynthesis Pathway u...
Β 
Multivariate Analysis of Tea (Camellia sinensis (L.) O. Kuntze) Clones on Mor...
Multivariate Analysis of Tea (Camellia sinensis (L.) O. Kuntze) Clones on Mor...Multivariate Analysis of Tea (Camellia sinensis (L.) O. Kuntze) Clones on Mor...
Multivariate Analysis of Tea (Camellia sinensis (L.) O. Kuntze) Clones on Mor...
Β 
Causes, Consequences and Remedies of Juvenile Delinquency in the Context of S...
Causes, Consequences and Remedies of Juvenile Delinquency in the Context of S...Causes, Consequences and Remedies of Juvenile Delinquency in the Context of S...
Causes, Consequences and Remedies of Juvenile Delinquency in the Context of S...
Β 
The Knowledge of and Attitude to and Beliefs about Causes and Treatments of M...
The Knowledge of and Attitude to and Beliefs about Causes and Treatments of M...The Knowledge of and Attitude to and Beliefs about Causes and Treatments of M...
The Knowledge of and Attitude to and Beliefs about Causes and Treatments of M...
Β 
Effect of Phosphorus and Zinc on the Growth, Nodulation and Yield of Soybean ...
Effect of Phosphorus and Zinc on the Growth, Nodulation and Yield of Soybean ...Effect of Phosphorus and Zinc on the Growth, Nodulation and Yield of Soybean ...
Effect of Phosphorus and Zinc on the Growth, Nodulation and Yield of Soybean ...
Β 
Influence of Harvest Stage on Yield and Yield Components of Orange Fleshed Sw...
Influence of Harvest Stage on Yield and Yield Components of Orange Fleshed Sw...Influence of Harvest Stage on Yield and Yield Components of Orange Fleshed Sw...
Influence of Harvest Stage on Yield and Yield Components of Orange Fleshed Sw...
Β 
Performance evaluation of upland rice (Oryza sativa L.) and variability study...
Performance evaluation of upland rice (Oryza sativa L.) and variability study...Performance evaluation of upland rice (Oryza sativa L.) and variability study...
Performance evaluation of upland rice (Oryza sativa L.) and variability study...
Β 
Response of Hot Pepper (Capsicum Annuum L.) to Deficit Irrigation in Bennatse...
Response of Hot Pepper (Capsicum Annuum L.) to Deficit Irrigation in Bennatse...Response of Hot Pepper (Capsicum Annuum L.) to Deficit Irrigation in Bennatse...
Response of Hot Pepper (Capsicum Annuum L.) to Deficit Irrigation in Bennatse...
Β 
Harnessing the Power of Agricultural Waste: A Study of Sabo Market, Ikorodu, ...
Harnessing the Power of Agricultural Waste: A Study of Sabo Market, Ikorodu, ...Harnessing the Power of Agricultural Waste: A Study of Sabo Market, Ikorodu, ...
Harnessing the Power of Agricultural Waste: A Study of Sabo Market, Ikorodu, ...
Β 
Influence of Conferences and Job Rotation on Job Productivity of Library Staf...
Influence of Conferences and Job Rotation on Job Productivity of Library Staf...Influence of Conferences and Job Rotation on Job Productivity of Library Staf...
Influence of Conferences and Job Rotation on Job Productivity of Library Staf...
Β 
Scanning Electron Microscopic Structure and Composition of Urinary Calculi of...
Scanning Electron Microscopic Structure and Composition of Urinary Calculi of...Scanning Electron Microscopic Structure and Composition of Urinary Calculi of...
Scanning Electron Microscopic Structure and Composition of Urinary Calculi of...
Β 
Gentrification and its Effects on Minority Communities – A Comparative Case S...
Gentrification and its Effects on Minority Communities – A Comparative Case S...Gentrification and its Effects on Minority Communities – A Comparative Case S...
Gentrification and its Effects on Minority Communities – A Comparative Case S...
Β 
Oil and Fatty Acid Composition Analysis of Ethiopian Mustard (Brasicacarinata...
Oil and Fatty Acid Composition Analysis of Ethiopian Mustard (Brasicacarinata...Oil and Fatty Acid Composition Analysis of Ethiopian Mustard (Brasicacarinata...
Oil and Fatty Acid Composition Analysis of Ethiopian Mustard (Brasicacarinata...
Β 

Recently uploaded

Activity 01 - Artificial Culture (1).pdf
Activity 01 - Artificial Culture (1).pdfActivity 01 - Artificial Culture (1).pdf
Activity 01 - Artificial Culture (1).pdf
ciinovamais
Β 
The basics of sentences session 3pptx.pptx
The basics of sentences session 3pptx.pptxThe basics of sentences session 3pptx.pptx
The basics of sentences session 3pptx.pptx
heathfieldcps1
Β 

Recently uploaded (20)

Food safety_Challenges food safety laboratories_.pdf
Food safety_Challenges food safety laboratories_.pdfFood safety_Challenges food safety laboratories_.pdf
Food safety_Challenges food safety laboratories_.pdf
Β 
Dyslexia AI Workshop for Slideshare.pptx
Dyslexia AI Workshop for Slideshare.pptxDyslexia AI Workshop for Slideshare.pptx
Dyslexia AI Workshop for Slideshare.pptx
Β 
Single or Multiple melodic lines structure
Single or Multiple melodic lines structureSingle or Multiple melodic lines structure
Single or Multiple melodic lines structure
Β 
UGC NET Paper 1 Mathematical Reasoning & Aptitude.pdf
UGC NET Paper 1 Mathematical Reasoning & Aptitude.pdfUGC NET Paper 1 Mathematical Reasoning & Aptitude.pdf
UGC NET Paper 1 Mathematical Reasoning & Aptitude.pdf
Β 
Unit-V; Pricing (Pharma Marketing Management).pptx
Unit-V; Pricing (Pharma Marketing Management).pptxUnit-V; Pricing (Pharma Marketing Management).pptx
Unit-V; Pricing (Pharma Marketing Management).pptx
Β 
Holdier Curriculum Vitae (April 2024).pdf
Holdier Curriculum Vitae (April 2024).pdfHoldier Curriculum Vitae (April 2024).pdf
Holdier Curriculum Vitae (April 2024).pdf
Β 
General Principles of Intellectual Property: Concepts of Intellectual Proper...
General Principles of Intellectual Property: Concepts of Intellectual  Proper...General Principles of Intellectual Property: Concepts of Intellectual  Proper...
General Principles of Intellectual Property: Concepts of Intellectual Proper...
Β 
Explore beautiful and ugly buildings. Mathematics helps us create beautiful d...
Explore beautiful and ugly buildings. Mathematics helps us create beautiful d...Explore beautiful and ugly buildings. Mathematics helps us create beautiful d...
Explore beautiful and ugly buildings. Mathematics helps us create beautiful d...
Β 
Basic Civil Engineering first year Notes- Chapter 4 Building.pptx
Basic Civil Engineering first year Notes- Chapter 4 Building.pptxBasic Civil Engineering first year Notes- Chapter 4 Building.pptx
Basic Civil Engineering first year Notes- Chapter 4 Building.pptx
Β 
Unit-IV- Pharma. Marketing Channels.pptx
Unit-IV- Pharma. Marketing Channels.pptxUnit-IV- Pharma. Marketing Channels.pptx
Unit-IV- Pharma. Marketing Channels.pptx
Β 
ICT Role in 21st Century Education & its Challenges.pptx
ICT Role in 21st Century Education & its Challenges.pptxICT Role in 21st Century Education & its Challenges.pptx
ICT Role in 21st Century Education & its Challenges.pptx
Β 
Making communications land - Are they received and understood as intended? we...
Making communications land - Are they received and understood as intended? we...Making communications land - Are they received and understood as intended? we...
Making communications land - Are they received and understood as intended? we...
Β 
HMCS Max Bernays Pre-Deployment Brief (May 2024).pptx
HMCS Max Bernays Pre-Deployment Brief (May 2024).pptxHMCS Max Bernays Pre-Deployment Brief (May 2024).pptx
HMCS Max Bernays Pre-Deployment Brief (May 2024).pptx
Β 
2024-NATIONAL-LEARNING-CAMP-AND-OTHER.pptx
2024-NATIONAL-LEARNING-CAMP-AND-OTHER.pptx2024-NATIONAL-LEARNING-CAMP-AND-OTHER.pptx
2024-NATIONAL-LEARNING-CAMP-AND-OTHER.pptx
Β 
SKILL OF INTRODUCING THE LESSON MICRO SKILLS.pptx
SKILL OF INTRODUCING THE LESSON MICRO SKILLS.pptxSKILL OF INTRODUCING THE LESSON MICRO SKILLS.pptx
SKILL OF INTRODUCING THE LESSON MICRO SKILLS.pptx
Β 
Kodo Millet PPT made by Ghanshyam bairwa college of Agriculture kumher bhara...
Kodo Millet  PPT made by Ghanshyam bairwa college of Agriculture kumher bhara...Kodo Millet  PPT made by Ghanshyam bairwa college of Agriculture kumher bhara...
Kodo Millet PPT made by Ghanshyam bairwa college of Agriculture kumher bhara...
Β 
Activity 01 - Artificial Culture (1).pdf
Activity 01 - Artificial Culture (1).pdfActivity 01 - Artificial Culture (1).pdf
Activity 01 - Artificial Culture (1).pdf
Β 
Graduate Outcomes Presentation Slides - English
Graduate Outcomes Presentation Slides - EnglishGraduate Outcomes Presentation Slides - English
Graduate Outcomes Presentation Slides - English
Β 
The basics of sentences session 3pptx.pptx
The basics of sentences session 3pptx.pptxThe basics of sentences session 3pptx.pptx
The basics of sentences session 3pptx.pptx
Β 
On National Teacher Day, meet the 2024-25 Kenan Fellows
On National Teacher Day, meet the 2024-25 Kenan FellowsOn National Teacher Day, meet the 2024-25 Kenan Fellows
On National Teacher Day, meet the 2024-25 Kenan Fellows
Β 

A New Keynesian Model with Estimated Shadow Rate for Japan Economy

  • 1. A New Keynesian Model with Estimated Shadow Rate for Japan Economy A New Keynesian Model with Estimated Shadow Rate for Japan Economy Rui WANG Assistant Professor at Department of Economics, Kanto Gakuen University, 200 Fujiaku-cho, Ota, Gunma Prefecture, 373-0034, Japan E-mail: kizuna.wr@gmail.com; Tel: +81-0276-32-7850 In this paper, we use Japanese government bond yield curve data to estimate the shadow rate from a shadow rate term structure model. We firstly confirm the traceability of shadow rate as a consistent and compatible measure of monetary policy which can be used to gauge the stance of monetary policy implemented by Bank of Japan, then we introduce shadow rate in a standard New Keynesian DSGE model and estimate the model using shadow rate estimated previously. Finally, we check the empirical results from the New Keynesian model. Empirical results show a good compatibility of the shadow rate used as a proxy of monetary policy in the estimation of New Keynesian model, providing credible policy implications as the benchmark New Keynesian model does in a standard context without the restriction of zero lower bound. Also, it has been shown that the monetary easing policy conducted by Bank of Japan has significantly positive effects on the improvement of the output gap and deflation. Using the shadow rate in the estimation of DSGE models also avoids the technical difficulties incurred by the nonlinearity of the zero lower bound. Key Words: shadow rate, New Keynesian model, unconventional monetary policy, Bank of Japan, zero lower bound JEL classification: E32, E44, E52 INTRODUCTION When the short-term nominal interest rate is at or near zero, central banks have to face the problems incurred by the Zero Lower Bound (ZLB) because the ZLB invalidates the implementation of conventional monetary policy, the adjustment of short-term policy rate. Facing the constraint of ZLB, central banks conduct unconventional monetary policy to stabilize and stimulate the economy. This is what Japan economy has experienced and Bank of Japan (BoJ) has done since 1999 when the call rate decreased to a very low level near zero. The Great Recession incurred by the Global Financial Crisis 2007-2009 brought the same problem to US, UK and Euro area. Besides the practical policy issues faced by the monetary authorities in advanced economies, the ZLB and the related unconventional monetary policy also pose academic issues and new challenges for macroeconomic research. New Keynesian Dynamic Stochastic General Equilibrium (NK-DSGE) model and Gaussian Affine Term Structure (GATS) model are two main workhorses in modern monetary macroeconomics and macro-finance. But when the ZLB on the short-term nominal interest rate binds, unfortunately, these models have deficient performance and undesired economic implications, leading to implausible and weird policy paradoxes and unsatisfied fitness of data. As a standard methodology for monetary policy analysis, a NK-DSGE model in the ZLB environment predicts that positive temporary supply from supply side of economy have contractionary effects and vice versa, negative shocks from supply side of economy have expansionary effects. Also, fiscal and forward guidance multipliers can be implausibly larger than one. But empirical works such as Wieland (2015) and GarΓ­n et al. (2019) showed similar impulse responses of output to a supply shock in both ZLB and non-ZLB environment. All these conclusions from the standard NK-DSGE models are inconsistent with economic intuition and empirical facts. Besides the misleading policy implications, the ZLB also Research Article Vol. 5(1), pp. 106-114, June, 2019. Β© www.premierpublishers.org. ISSN: 3012-8103 World Journal of Economics and Finance
  • 2. A New Keynesian Model with Estimated Shadow Rate for Japan Economy Wang R. 107 brings many technical problems in DSGE methodology. The explicit introduction of the ZLB constraint into DSGE models accompanies with structural break or nonlinear kink. Such kind of nonlinearity invalidates the linear approximation and the Kalman filter. Some researchers use global projection method and the particle filter to deal with the nonlinearity in solution and estimation of DSGE models, but these methods are technically difficult and demand for numerous computations. As another main methodology in macro-finance research, GATS models which are widely used to fit the term structure of interest rate can provide good description of the dynamics of short interest rate in many macro-financial applications in the non-ZLB environment, but in the ZLB environment, the GATS models provide barely satisfactory fitness of data and cannot accommodate the "sticky" property of short interest rate. This "sticky" property means that the short- term interest rates tend to keep approximately static around the ZLB with lower volatilities for a long period of time. LITERATURE REVIEW In recent research, the Shadow Rate Term Structure (SRTS) model which was firstly proposed by Black (1995) has become an alternative to overcome the poor performance incurred by the ZLB in general GATS model. Kim and Singleton (2012) and Bauer and Rudebusch (2013) have used the shadow rate estimated from a SRTS model to capture the behavior of interest rates and the stance of unconventional monetary policy in the ZLB environment. Krippner (2013) proposed a continuous-time formulation of SRTS model, known as Krippner Affine Gaussian model (K-AGM), where he added a call option feature to derive the closed-form solution. Wu and Xia (2016) took an analogous discrete-time approach which can be directly applied to discrete-time yield curve data without any numerical error associated with simulation methods and numerical integration in other models. All of these literatures advocate the effectiveness of the shadow rate as a kind of measure for describing the monetary policy stance. Wu and Zhang (2016) established the equivalence between shadow rate and unconventional monetary policy in a standard NK-DSGE model. The equivalence between shadow rate and unconventional monetary policy is established on the empirical findings that have shown the highly correlation between the quantity of government bond purchase and the estimated shadow rate. The shadow rate can take both positive and negative values and show consistent response to monetary policy in both non-ZLB and ZLB environment. Introducing the shadow rate into a DSGE model can provide more insights for the propagation and amplification mechanism of unconventional monetary policy without introducing the complications incurred by the ZLB constraint. Methodology, Hypothesis and Main Conclusions We take a combination of these two methods, using the shadow rate estimated from a SRTS model as the data for the estimation of a NK-DSGE model where the general policy rate is replaced by the shadow rate. Then we use the NK-DSGE model with shadow rate to do some monetary policy analysis for Japan economy. This may be a circuitous route, but the logic is valid and consistent from the beginning to the end. Also, this approach salvages the DSGE models from the nonlinearity incurred by the ZLB. Standard procedures such as the linear approximation and the Kalman filter can be used instead of complicated nonlinear solution and estimation techniques. The main hypothesis in this paper is that can we use the shadow rate as a proxy of monetary policy in the monetary policy analysis with DSGE models without considering the technical difficulties of zero lower bound explicitly. Main conclusion from this paper is that we can still use general linear solution and estimation techniques of DSGE models in the monetary policy analysis by introducing the concept of shadow rate with a semi-structural approach proposed by Wu and Zhang (2016). Estimation results from full- sample and sub-sample shows that the structural parameters are quite robust in the Bayesian estimation with the estimated shadow rate. Also, historical decomposition and impulse response also advocate the effectiveness of the unconventional monetary policy conducted by the BoJ. The remaining of this paper is organized as follows. Section 1 presents the estimation of shadow rate from a SRTS model of Krippner (2013). We also check the shadow rate's traceability as a summary for monetary policy. In Section 2, we estimate a New Keynesian DSGE model with shadow rate. Section 3 checks the empirical results such as historical decomposition and impulse response from the estimated DSGE model. Section 4 concludes this paper and gives the prospect for further research. 1. Shadow Rate Bauer and Rudebusch (2013) and Christensen and Rudebusch (2014) pointed out that the estimated shadow rates vary across different model specifications and estimation methods. Kim and Singleton (2012) and Bauer and Rudebusch (2013) use simulation-based estimation method to estimate the shadow rate. Krippner (2013) and Wu and Xia (2016) estimated an analogous SRTS model, but with different time specifications, the former is in continuous-time and the the latter is in discrete-time. Krippner (2013) and Wu and Xia (2016) pose their estimation codes on Internet. By replicating the estimation of shadow rates for US, UK, Japan and EU, the results don't show much difference in two methods. Ichiue and Ueno (2013)'s estimation is based on the approximation of bond prices by ignoring Jensen's inequality. Imakubo and Nakajima (2015) also estimated a shadow rate model to
  • 3. A New Keynesian Model with Estimated Shadow Rate for Japan Economy World J. Econ. Fin. 108 extract inflation risk premium from nominal and real term structures. By surveying related literature and replicating the estimation results, we find that although the shadow rates estimated from different model specifications and estimation methods do have different values, they show common trend and dynamics and lead to same economic implications in the analysis of monetary policy, at least for the major advanced economies, US, UK, Japan and Euro area. Also, most existing literatures advocate the potential usefulness of shadow rate as a measure for the stance of monetary policy. Bullard (2012), Krippner (2012), Lombardi and Zhu (2014) and Wu and Xia (2016) all support the view that the shadow rate is a powerful tool to summarize useful information from yield curve data and describe the conventional monetary policy stance in the non-ZLB environment and unconventional monetary policy stance in the ZLB environment in a consistent manner. 1.1. Estimation of Shadow Rate Krippner (2012, 2013, 2014, 2015a, 2015b) provide a detailed introduction of his methodology of term structure modeling of shadow rate. For derivation of the model, please refer to Krippner (2015b). We use yield curve data of Japanese government bond to estimate the shadow rate. See Table 1 for the summary statistics of yield curve data. Table 1: Summary Statistics of Japan Yield Curve Data Maturity 3M 6M 1Y 2Y 3Y 4Y Mean 0.46 0.47 0.51 0.63 0.77 0.94 Med 0.12 0.13 0.15 0.25 0.40 0.57 Max 4.29 4.17 4.16 4.24 4.41 4.95 Min -0.42 -0.43 -0.37 -0.36 -0.36 -0.36 Std. Dev 0.85 0.83 0.85 0.90 0.97 1.06 Obs. 6360 6360 6360 6360 6360 6360 Maturity 5Y 7Y 10Y 15Y 20Y 30Y Mean 1.10 1.40 1.81 2.13 2.53 2.70 Med 0.73 1.03 1.49 1.83 2.20 2.48 Max 5.25 5.71 5.64 6.16 6.44 6.24 Min -0.37 -0.39 -0.28 -0.13 0.03 0.05 Std. Dev 1.13 1.22 1.26 1.29 1.26 1.16 Obs. 6360 6360 6360 6360 6360 6360 The Figure 1 shows the plot of data from which we can find that since 1999, the yield curve has shifted down to very low level. The 3-months bond yield has begun to take negative values since 2014M10. The yield curve data of Japan is Japanese government bond data from 1992-Jul- 10 to 2016-Nov-24, daily frequency of 5-business days week with 6360 observations, obtained from the Bloomberg database. The maturity of yield curve is from 3- months to 30-years and 3-months interest rate is adapted to be the short interest rate, which is almost same as the short policy rate of BoJ. Interest rates with other maturities can be represented as a function of short interest rate and forward rate in term structure models. The Figure 2 gives the estimation result of shadow rate. The full series of daily estimation for shadow rate from 1992-Jul-10 is available upon request. We did the daily-frequency estimation of the shadow rate and aggregated the daily-frequency data to average monthly-frequency data. The gray shaded band around the point estimate (red line in Figure 2) is the 95% of the confidence interval. During non-ZLB period, the shadow rate and call rate have almost same dynamics. The shadow rate shows a good approximation to the call rate. But during the ZLB period, the call rate is approximately near to zero. We can't read too much information about monetary policy from the call rate. But the shadow rate has keeping decreasing. In next section, we check the relation between the shadow rate and the balance sheet of BoJ. Besides other unconventional operations of the central bank, such as forward guidance and direct facility lending, the enlargement of balance sheet, widely known as quantitative easing (QE), is the essence of unconventional monetary policy, especially for the monetary policy of BoJ. Figure 1: Yield Curve Data of Japanese Government Bond Figure 2: Estimated Shadow Rate, Call Rate and 3- months Bond Interest Rate 1.2. Empirical Evidence of Shadow Rate We establish some empirical relations between the shadow rate and the balance sheet.
  • 4. A New Keynesian Model with Estimated Shadow Rate for Japan Economy Wang R. 109 Figure 3: Balance Sheet of BoJ BoJ is the first central bank which introduced unconventional monetary policy among major advanced economies. Table 2 summarizes the monetary policy regimes of BoJ since 1999. The essence of the policy programs conducted by BoJ is the large scale purchase of Japanese government bond. From the Figure 3, we can find since 2010M10, the balance sheet of BoJ has increased aggressively. What is the relation between the shadow rate and the size of balance sheet? Table 2: Monetary Policy Regimes of BoJ 1999/2/2-2000/8/11: Zero Interest Rate Policy (pink shaded area in Figure 4) 20013/19-2006/3/9: Quantitative Easing (yellow shaded area in Figure 4) 2010/10/5-2013/3/20: Comprehensive Monetary Easing (green shaded area in Figure 4) 20134/4-2016/1/29: Price Stability Target of 2% and Quantitative and Qualitative Monetary Easing (blue shaded area in Figure 4) 2016/2/16-2016/9/19: Price Stability Target of 2% and Quantitative and Qualitative Monetary Easing with a Negative Interest Rate 2016/9/21- Now: Price Stability Target of 2% and Quantitative and Qualitative Monetary Easing with Yield Curve Control The Figure 4 shows the time series plot of shadow rate, minus log of bond holdings and minus log of monetary base. Figure 4: Shadow Rate and Balance Sheet The correlation between shadow rate and bond holdings is -0.81 and the correlation between shadow rate and monetary base is -0.82. The X-Y scatter plots also show obviously negative correlation between the shadow rate and the variables of balance sheet. Note that the shadow rate can't be controlled directly by the central bank in the ZLB environment. In the non-ZLB environment, the shadow rate takes positive value which is same to the general short-term policy rate. The short-term policy rate can be controlled by the central bank through open market operations. What the central bank can manipulate is its balance sheet. The shadow rate just summarizes the stance of policy. According to the empirical relation between the shadow rate and the balance sheet, we can map the manipulation of the balance sheet into the change of the shadow rate. 2. Shadow Rate NK-DSGE Model In this section, we first derive a standard NK-DSGE model, then we incorporate the shadow rate into this standard framework. We show that the shadow rate can be used as an equivalence for QE so we can use the NK-DSGE model with shadow rate to analyze the unconventional monetary policy without considering the technical complexity incurred by the ZLB. 2.1. Standard NK-DSGE Model We assume that representative household maximizes the discounted life-time utility 𝐸𝑑 βˆ‘ [ 𝐢𝑑 1βˆ’πœŽ 1βˆ’πœŽ βˆ’ χ𝐿 𝑑 1+πœ‚ 1+πœ‚ ]∞ 𝑑=0 subject to budget constraint 𝐢𝑑 + 𝐡𝑑 𝑃 𝑑 ≀ 𝑅 π‘‘βˆ’1 𝐡 π΅π‘‘βˆ’1 𝑃 𝑑 + π‘Šπ‘‘ 𝐿 𝑑 + 𝑇𝑑 where 𝐢𝑑 , 𝐿 𝑑, 𝐡𝑑, π‘Šπ‘‘, 𝑇𝑑, 𝑅𝑑 𝐡 represent consumption, labor, bond, real wage, lump-sum transfer and private interest rate respectively. 𝜎 is the inverse of inter-temporal substitution of consumption and πœ‚ is the inverse of Frisch elasticity of labor supply. The representative household discounts the utility with objective discount factor 𝛽. Final-good firms produce homogenous final-goods with CES-type production function π‘Œπ‘‘ = [∫ π‘Œπ‘—,𝑑 Ξ΅βˆ’1 πœ€ 𝑑𝑗 1 0 ] πœ€ πœ€βˆ’1 where π‘Œπ‘—,𝑑 is an intermediate-good produced by intermediate-good firm. πœ€ is the elasticity of substitution among differentiated intermediate-goods. Intermediate-good firms use Cobb- Douglas production technology π‘Œπ‘—,𝑑 = 𝐴 𝑑 𝐿𝑗,𝑑 1βˆ’π›Ό to produce heterogenous intermediate-goods where 𝐴 𝑑 is total factor productivity (TFP) that is common to all intermediate-good firms. As a basic setup in standard NK-DSGE model, sticky price is introduced by Calvo (1983)’s staggered price setting mechanism. For the details of derivation, please refer to Gali (2015), Walsh (2017) and Miao (2014). After solving the optimization problems of each economic agent, finally, the standard NK-DSGE model can be represented by two equations, New Keynesian IS equation describing the dynamics of output gap π‘₯𝑑 which can be derived from the inter-temporal optimization of household.
  • 5. A New Keynesian Model with Estimated Shadow Rate for Japan Economy World J. Econ. Fin. 110 π‘₯𝑑 = 𝐸𝑑 π‘₯𝑑+1 βˆ’ 1 𝜎 (π‘Ÿπ‘‘ 𝐡 βˆ’ 𝐸𝑑 πœ‹ 𝑑+1 βˆ’ π‘Ÿπ‘‘ 𝑁) (1) and the New Keynesian Phillips Curve (NKPC) equation describing the dynamics of inflation πœ‹ 𝑑 which can be derived from the Calvo (1983)’s price setting mechanism. πœ‹ 𝑑 = 𝛽𝐸𝑑 πœ‹ 𝑑+1 + πœ…π‘₯𝑑 (2) Output gap π‘₯𝑑 is defined as the difference between output under sticky price decentralized equilibrium and output under flexible price decentralized equilibrium. ΞΊ = (1βˆ’πœƒ)(1βˆ’π›½πœƒ)[πœ‚+𝛼+𝜎(1βˆ’π›Ό)] πœƒ(1βˆ’π›Ό+πœ€π›Ό) is a composite of deep structural parameters. We introduce the economic explanations of these deep structural parameters in next section. π‘Ÿπ‘‘ 𝑁 is Natural interest rate which is determined by exogenous TFP process 𝐴 𝑑 in the standard context of New Keynesian mode. 2.2. Shadow Rate in NK-DSGE Model According to the empirical evidence of shadow rate presented in Section 2, we introduce shadow rate into standard NK-DSGE model. For general NK-DSGE model, the economic agents face risk-free short rate π‘Ÿπ‘‘ and hold risk-free bond. π‘Ÿπ‘‘ is generally recognized as the short policy rate which can be controlled by the central bank. In actual, the relevant interest rates affecting economic agents’ decisions are private interest rates π‘Ÿπ‘‘ 𝐡 through which both conventional and unconventional monetary policies transmit into the economy. Generally, the private interest rates π‘Ÿπ‘‘ 𝐡 can be represented as the sum of risk- free short rate π‘Ÿπ‘‘ plus a time-varying risk premium π‘Ÿπ‘‘ 𝑃 , π‘Ÿπ‘‘ 𝐡 = π‘Ÿπ‘‘ + π‘Ÿπ‘‘ 𝑃 , where π‘Ÿπ‘‘ is assumed that can be adjusted by the conventional monetary policy of the central bank. Empirical works such as Gagnon et al. (2011), Krishnamurthy and Vissing-Jorgensen (2012) and Hamilton and Wu (2012) advocate that the large-scale asset purchase by the central banks can reduce the risk premium which means βˆ‚rt P βˆ‚bt G < 0 where 𝑏𝑑 𝐺 is the log of bond holdings of the central bank. This is known as the risk premium channel of QE. Figure 5: Credit Spread and Balance Sheet The Figure 5 shows the relation between credit spread and the balance sheet. The credit spread used here is defined as the difference between 10-years and 2-years Japanese government bond returns. The correlation between credit spread and log of bond holdings is -0.80 and the correlation of credit spread and log of monetary base is - 0.81. According to the regression lines in Figure 5, we assume that the response of risk premium π‘Ÿπ‘‘ 𝑃 to bond holdings 𝑏𝑑 𝐺 follows a simple linear form π‘Ÿπ‘‘ 𝑃 = π‘Ÿ 𝑃 βˆ’ Ξ³(𝑏𝑑 𝐺 βˆ’ 𝑏 𝐺) + Ξ΅ 𝑑 𝑃 where βˆ’Ξ³ = πœ•π‘Ÿπ‘‘ 𝑃 βˆ‚bt G < 0 , π‘Ÿ 𝑃 is the constant component of risk premium and πœ€π‘‘ 𝑃 is the exogenous time- varying component of risk premium which is interpreted as the liquidity preference shock in Campbell et al. (2017). In the non-ZLB environment, 𝑏𝑑 𝐺 = 𝑏 𝐺 , π‘Ÿπ‘‘ 𝑃 = π‘Ÿ 𝑃 + πœ€π‘‘ 𝑃 such that π‘Ÿπ‘‘ 𝐡 = π‘Ÿπ‘‘ + π‘Ÿπ‘‘ 𝑃 = π‘Ÿπ‘‘ + π‘Ÿ 𝑃 + πœ€π‘‘ 𝑃 which means that the private interest rate is the short rate controlled by the central bank plus risk premium. When π‘Ÿπ‘‘ is restricted by the ZLB, approximately π‘Ÿπ‘‘ = 0 and π‘Ÿπ‘‘ 𝐡 = π‘Ÿ 𝑃 βˆ’ 𝛾(𝑏𝑑 𝐺 βˆ’ 𝑏 𝐺) + πœ€π‘‘ 𝑃 through which the unconventional monetary policy affects risk premium to reduce private interest rate and stimulate the economy. According to the empirical evidence of the shadow rate, we also assume that the shadow rate has a same response to the log of bond holdings in a linear form like 𝑠𝑑 = βˆ’Ξ³(𝑏𝑑 𝐺 βˆ’ 𝑏 𝐺), then π‘Ÿπ‘‘ 𝐡 = 𝑠𝑑 + π‘Ÿ 𝑃 + Ξ΅ 𝑑 𝑃 can capture the both conventional and unconventional monetary policies. In the non-ZLB environment, st = rt > 0 , bt G = bG and rt B = rt + rP + Ξ΅t P , the New Keynesian IS curve is π‘₯𝑑 = 𝐸𝑑 π‘₯𝑑+1 βˆ’ 1 Οƒ (π‘Ÿπ‘‘ 𝐡 βˆ’ 𝐸𝑑π 𝑑+1 βˆ’ π‘Ÿπ‘‘ 𝑁) = 𝐸𝑑 π‘₯𝑑+1 βˆ’ 1 𝜎 (π‘Ÿπ‘‘ + π‘Ÿ 𝑃 + πœ€π‘‘ 𝑃 βˆ’ 𝐸𝑑 πœ‹ 𝑑+1 βˆ’ π‘Ÿπ‘‘ 𝑁) = 𝐸𝑑 π‘₯𝑑+1 βˆ’ 1 𝜎 (π‘Ÿπ‘‘ βˆ’ 𝐸𝑑 πœ‹ 𝑑+1) + πœ€π‘‘ π‘₯ = 𝐸𝑑 π‘₯𝑑+1 βˆ’ 1 𝜎 (𝑠𝑑 βˆ’ 𝐸𝑑 πœ‹ 𝑑+1) + πœ€π‘‘ π‘₯ (3) where Ξ΅t x = βˆ’ 1 Οƒ (rP + Ξ΅t P βˆ’ rt N) is a compound of exogenous shocks. The risk premium shock π‘Ÿπ‘‘ 𝑃 and rt N can't be identified separately, so we denote the compound of these exogenous shocks as a demand shock Ξ΅t x . In the ZLB environment, the New Keynesian IS curve is π‘₯𝑑 = 𝐸𝑑 π‘₯𝑑+1 βˆ’ 1 Οƒ (π‘Ÿπ‘‘ 𝐡 βˆ’ 𝐸𝑑π 𝑑+1 βˆ’ π‘Ÿπ‘‘ 𝑁) = 𝐸𝑑 π‘₯𝑑+1 βˆ’ 1 Οƒ (𝑠𝑑 + π‘Ÿ 𝑃 + Ξ΅ 𝑑 𝑃 βˆ’ 𝐸𝑑π 𝑑+1 βˆ’ π‘Ÿπ‘‘ 𝑁) = 𝐸𝑑 π‘₯𝑑+1 βˆ’ 1 Οƒ (𝑠𝑑 βˆ’ 𝐸𝑑π 𝑑+1) + Ξ΅ 𝑑 π‘₯ (4) which is same as its counterpart in the non-ZLB environment. We can find that from equation (3) and (4), New Keynesian IS curve with shadow rate has the same specification in both ZLB environment and non-ZLB environment. Finally, we define a Taylor rule of shadow rate with interest rate smoothing
  • 6. A New Keynesian Model with Estimated Shadow Rate for Japan Economy Wang R. 111 𝑠𝑑 = Ο† 𝑠 π‘ π‘‘βˆ’1 + (1 βˆ’ Ο† 𝑠)(Ο† π‘₯ π‘₯𝑑 + φππ 𝑑) + Ξ΅ 𝑑 𝑠 (5) where Ξ΅t s is the monetary policy shock and φπ > 1 guarantees a unique, non-explosive equilibrium. 2.3. Estimation of NK-DSGE Model with Shadow Rate From the analysis in Section 3.2, we can find the NK- DSGE model with shadow rate has the same formulation in both ZLB and non-ZLB environment given equation (3) and equation (4). Because we have three observable variables, output gap, inflation rate and shadow rate, we add a shock term to the New Keynesian Phillips Curve (equation (2)) to avoid the stochastic singularity in estimation. According to Gali (2015, chapter 4), the shock term can be explained as a cost-push shock which may come from the exogenous variations in desired price markups or exogenous variations in wage markups. The main model is given in equation (6), (7), (8) and (9). π‘₯𝑑 = 𝐸𝑑 π‘₯𝑑+1 βˆ’ 1 Οƒ (𝑠𝑑 βˆ’ 𝐸𝑑π 𝑑+1) + Ξ΅ 𝑑 π‘₯ (6) Ο€ 𝑑 = β𝐸𝑑π 𝑑+1 + ΞΊπ‘₯𝑑 + Ξ΅ 𝑑 Ο€ (7) 𝑠𝑑 = Ο† 𝑠 π‘ π‘‘βˆ’1 + (1 βˆ’ Ο† 𝑠)(Ο† π‘₯ π‘₯𝑑 + φππ 𝑑) + Ξ΅ 𝑑 𝑠 (8) All shocks follow first-order autoregressive processes Ξ΅ 𝑑 shock = ρshockΞ΅ π‘‘βˆ’1 shock + μ𝑑 shock , shock ∈ (π‘₯, Ο€, 𝑠) (9) where ΞΌt shock ∼ N(0, Οƒshock 2 ) is exogenous innovation term. Figure 6: Data for Estimation The data used for output gap π‘₯𝑑 in equation (6) which is official estimate obtained from BoJ is from 1983Q1 to 2016Q3. The data series of inflation πœ‹ 𝑑 in equation (7) is GDP deflator-based inflation rate from 1980Q3 to 2016Q3. The data series of shadow rate in equation (8) is from 1999Q1 to 2016Q3. For non-ZLB period from 1983Q1 to 1998Q4, the shadow rate is replaced by the non-ZLB constrained call rate to complete the full data series of interest rate. Some structural parameters are calibratedfootnote as 𝛼 = 0, 𝛽 = 0.9975, πœ€ = 6 and 𝜎 = πœ‚ = 1. The elasticity of substitution πœ€ is calibrated to be 6 which means an average 20% markup charged by intermediate-good firms at steady state. 𝜎 and πœ‚ are calibrated at 1 because these parameters can't be identified in the Bayesian estimation. 𝛼 = 0 means the model economy has the constant scale to return. πœ… is a composite of other structural parameters and we specify its prior distribution as non-informative uniform prior distribution U(0,1). The prior and posterior distributions of parameters and standard deviations are given in Table 3. We estimate the NK-DSGE in a DSGE-VAR style to compare the theoretical impulse response from DSGE model and corresponding empirical impulse response from Bayesian VAR model. Please refer to Del Negro and Shorfheide (2004), Adjemian et al. (2008), Del negro et al. (2007) for the technical details of DSGE-VAR model. The basic idea of the DSGE-VAR(πœ†) is to use the empirical moments implied from a structural-from DSGE model as the prior distribution for a Bayesian VAR model. When choosing the prior distribution of a reduced-form Bayesian VAR model, πœ† is the weight of this constraint of empirical moments implied from the DSGE model. Following Adjemian et al. (2008), we treat πœ† as a parameter which can be jointly estimated from the Bayesian estimation of other structural parameters and specify the prior distribution of πœ† as non-informative uniform prior distribution U(0,2). Also, we compare the impulse response and calculate the historical decomposition to check the contribution of the shadow rate monetary policy shock to output gap and inflation. The posterior distributions of structural parameters are consistent with most of related literature on the NK-DSGE estimation with non-ZLB constrained policy rate. For example, given posterior mean of πœ… and other calibrated structural parameters, we can calculate πœƒ as πœƒ = 1 2 (Θ βˆ’ √Θ2 βˆ’ 4) where Θ = 1 + 1 𝛽 + πœ… 𝛽(πœ‚+𝜎) . πœƒ represents probability that an intermediate-good firm can't optimize its price in the Calvo (1983)’s staggered price setting framework. We find that πœƒ = 0.7313 means the duration of price optimization is almost 11 months (3.7 quarters), which is quite reasonable and consistent with most empirical findings about the price adjustment. The multivariate convergence diagnostic also shows good convergence for all parameters. As a check of robustness, we also give the estimation results from the 1999Q1- 2016Q3 sub-sample. The structural parameters still have reasonable values and impulse response of monetary policy also shows consistent dynamics of variables. But if we use the ZLB-constrained call rate for sub-sample estimation in the same period, we can't get any reasonable results because it is almost impossible for a linear NK- DSGE model, without using nonlinear techniques, to capture the information of monetary policy from the ZLB- constrained call rate with less dynamics. 3. Shadow Rate NK-DSGE Model in Monetary Policy Analysis By introducing the concept of shadow rate into a standard NK-DSGE model and estimating it with the shadow rate, the monetary policy analysis in the ZLB environment can be done in a same way as the analysis in the non-ZLB environment. We run some standard procedures of DSGE methodology. Firstly, we show the historical decomposition to check the contributions of each shock 3.1. Historical Decomposition From the Figure 7, we can confirm the effects of monetary policy represented by shadow rate, especially from 2014.
  • 7. A New Keynesian Model with Estimated Shadow Rate for Japan Economy World J. Econ. Fin. 112 Table 3: Bayesian Estimation of Structural Parameters Prior Distribution Posterior Distribution (1980Q3-20016Q3 sample) Posterior Distribution (1991Q1-2016Q3 sample) Parameters Mean St.Dev. Prior Mean St.Dev. 90% HPD Mean St.Dev. 90% HPD πœ‘ πœ‹ 1.5 0.1 G 1.4895 0.1264 [1.2786,1.6923] 1.4679 0.1035 [1.2925, 1.6328] πœ‘ π‘₯ 0.375 0.1 G 0.5896 0.1994 [0.2472,0.9084] 0.5839 0.1434 [0.3520, 0.8209] πœ‘π‘  0.8 0.1 B 0.8088 0.0341 [0.7557,0.8669] 0.8506 0.0281 [0.8050, 0.8959] 𝜌 πœ‹ 0.8 0.1 B 0.4835 0.1393 [0.2694,0.7190] 0.4475 0.0906 [0.2967, 0.5921] 𝜌 π‘₯ 0.8 0.1 B 0.7713 0.0800 [0.6460,0.9060] 0.7949 0.0658 [0.6906, 0.9022] πœŒπ‘  0.8 0.1 B 0.4868 0.0989 [0.3250,0.6457] 0.5421 0.0843 [0.4001, 0.6784 πœ‡ πœ‹ 0.5 0.5 IG 0.2011 0.0353 [0.1475,0.2613] 0.2424 0.0367 [0.1730, 0.2912] πœ‡ π‘₯ 0.5 0.5 IG 0.2057 0.0318 [0.1491,0.2517] 0.2325 0.0432 [0.1749, 0.3130] πœ‡ 𝑠 0.5 0.5 IG 0.1347 0.0160 [0.1096,0.1611] 0.1364 0.0168 [0.1088, 0.1629] Parameters Prior Distribution Mean St.Dev. 90% HPD Mean St.Dev. 90% HPD πœ… U(0,1) 0.1920 0.1741 [-0.0039,0.4726] 0.1058 0.0679 [0.0102, 0.2029] πœ† U(0,2) 0.5174 0.1001 [0.3518, 0.6619] 1.3958 0.3007 [0.9527, 1.9328] The positive contributions of the shadow rate monetary policy shock (red area in Figure 7) from 2014 confirm the effects of Quantitative Qualitative Monetary Easing (QQE) of BoJ. Figure 7: Historical Decomposition of Inflation Figure 8: Historical Decomposition of Output Gap Figure 8 shows the historical decompositions of inflation. The most of fluctuations of inflation come from the supply shock, demand shock and (shadow rate) monetary policy shock. Also, (shadow rate) monetary policy shock has positive contribution to positive inflation since 2014 (red area in Figure 8). We can conclude from the historical decompositions of output gap and inflation, the enlargement of balance sheet of BoJ does have its effect to improve the output gap and deflation. 3.2. Impulse Response Function Bayesian impulse response functions (IRFs) are calculated based on the posterior distributions of structural parameters and exogenous shock standard deviations. The gray shaded area represents the 90% Highest Posterior Density Interval (HPDI) of posterior impulse response calculated from DSGE model. The thick black line is the medium of posterior impulse response of DSGE model. The corresponding impulse response calculated from Bayesian VAR is also plotted in dashed lines with HPDI (90%) and the medium of impulse response inside the two dashed lines. We can find the posterior impulse response from DSGE model and VAR model has the almost same dynamics, similar range and direction, especially for inflation and (shadow) interest rate. Note that even the shadow rate can take negative values, the change of shadow rate, a rise or a reduction, still has the same effect as the positive policy rate has in the non-ZLB environment. The shadow rate NK-DSGE model shows consistent IRFs no matter the policy rate is restricted by the ZLB or not, both models show the output gap improves due to the expansionary monetary policy shock. Figure 9: IRF of negative (shadow rate) monetary policy shock πœ€π‘‘ 𝑠 Figure 10 shows the dynamic response of demand shock πœ€π‘‘ π‘₯ . A positive demand shock can improve the output gap. At the same time, monetary policy rule responses to the corresponding increasing of inflation and output gap with the increasing of (shadow) interest rate. Figure 10: IRF of demand shock πœ€π‘‘ π‘₯
  • 8. A New Keynesian Model with Estimated Shadow Rate for Japan Economy Wang R. 113 Figure 11 gives the supply shock (cost-push shock) πœ€π‘‘ πœ‹ which can trigger the increasing of inflation. Also, the (shadow) interest rate responses to the increasing of inflation, which is totally same compared to the standard context of NK-DSGE model. Figure 11: IRF of supply shock πœ€π‘‘ πœ‹ We find that all these empirical results are same to those in the standard NK-DSGE models although here we used the shadow rate to estimate the model. DISCUSSIONS In this paper, we estimated the shadow rate of Japan economy from a shadow rate term structure model. We adopt the shadow rate as a measure of monetary policy of BoJ because since 1999Q1, the general policy rate of BoJ, call rate, has kept been near zero and already lost its function as an operating target for the conduct of monetary policy. The concept of shadow rate is not new and for a long time, it is not widely used in macroeconomics. Since the ZLB has become a common issue for monetary authorities in the advanced economies, using the shadow rate to observe and analyze the monetary policy has been applied in many empirical works. We also confirmed that the shadow rate does have credible traceability of the BoJ's policy in the ZLB environment, providing us a new perspective to check the unconventional monetary policy of BoJ. Most of existing literatures use the shadow rate in reduced-form time series econometric models such as FAVAR or TVP-VAR to find the empirical evidences of unconventional monetary policy, but these models are not structural. The introduction of the shadow rate into the DSGE framework is a new attempt. Using the shadow rate does relieve us from the technical difficulties incurred by the ZLB, but whether this method is robust or not is still unclear. As far as we know, there doesn't exist other similar works that use the shadow rate in the estimation of DSGE model. However, the historical decomposition of output gap and inflation advocates the effectiveness of the monetary easing conducted by BoJ. The transmission channels of the monetary easing policy which are assumed in this paper are based on the empirical findings and these empirical evidences have been mapped into the model. Then we find that the impulse response functions of shadow rate NK-DSGE model are similar to the benchmark NK-DSGE model. The mechanism of the general policy rate and shadow rate is same as the standard NK-DSGE framework. Note that there may exist one defect in the estimation of DSGE models with shadow rate. It is that the shadow rate is not endogenously derived from a structural model, but exogenously estimated by a statistical model. SRTS model is a factor model and the factors are used to fit and describe the yield curve in a ZLB environment. But the factors have less economic interpretation. Krippner (2015) gives a structural interpretation of these factors in a linear economy framework, but this framework is highly stylized and has less dynamics than DSGE models. The estimation of the shadow rate by SRTS model needs nonlinear numerical calculations, this makes the endogenous determination of the shadow rate in a structural DSGE framework very difficult. For further research, we want to introduce the shadow rate to a Smets and Wouters (2003, 2007) type middle-scale DSGE model, which is the prototype of the DSGE models used in major central banks. Also, we shouldn't forget that the shadow rate only exists as an economic concept and the central bank can't control the shadow rate as an operating target, but we can use the information from it as a guidance for monetary policy operation. REFERENCES Adjemian, S., Darracq Paries, M., & Moyen, S. (2008). Towards a monetary policy evaluation framework (No. 942). European Central Bank. Bauer, M. D., & Rudebusch, G. D. (2013). The signaling channel for Federal Reserve bond purchases. International Journal of Central Banking, forthcoming. Black, F. (1995). Interest rates as options. the Journal of Finance, 50(5), 1371-1376. Bullard, J. (2012). Shadow interest rates and the stance of US monetary policy (No. 206). Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis. Campbell, J. R., Fisher, J. D., Justiniano, A., & Melosi, L. (2017). Forward guidance and macroeconomic outcomes since the financial crisis. NBER Macroeconomics Annual, 31(1), 283-357. Christensen, J. H., & Rudebusch, G. D. (2014). Estimating shadow-rate term structure models with near-zero yields. Journal of Financial Econometrics, 13(2), 226- 259. Del Negro, M., & Schorfheide, F. (2004). Priors from general equilibrium models for VARs. International Economic Review, 45(2), 643-673. Del Negro, M., Schorfheide, F., Smets, F., & Wouters, R. (2007). On the fit of new Keynesian models. Journal of Business & Economic Statistics, 25(2), 123-143. Gagnon, J., Raskin, M., Remache, J., & Sack, B. (2011). The financial market effects of the Federal Reserve’s large-scale asset purchases. international Journal of central Banking, 7(1), 3-43. GalΓ­, J. (2015). Monetary policy, inflation, and the business cycle: an introduction to the new Keynesian framework and its applications. Princeton University Press.
  • 9. A New Keynesian Model with Estimated Shadow Rate for Japan Economy World J. Econ. Fin. 114 GarΓ­n, J., Lester, R., & Sims, E. (2019). Are supply shocks contractionary at the ZLB? Evidence from utilization- adjusted TFP data. Review of Economics and Statistics, 101(1), 160-175. Hamilton, J. D., & Wu, J. C. (2012). The effectiveness of alternative monetary policy tools in a zero lower bound environment. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 44, 3-46. Ichiue, H., & Ueno, Y. (2013). Estimating term premia at the zero bound: An analysis of Japanese, US, and UK yields (No. 13-E-8). Bank of Japan. Imakubo, K., & Nakajima, J. (2015). Estimating inflation risk premia from nominal and real yield curves using a shadow-rate model (No. 15-E-1). Bank of Japan. Kim, D. H., & Singleton, K. J. (2012). Term structure models and the zero bound: an empirical investigation of Japanese yields. Journal of Econometrics, 170(1), 32-49. Krippner, L. (2012). Modifying Gaussian term structure models when interest rates are near the zero lower bound. Reserve Bank of New Zealand Discussion Paper, (2012/02). Krippner, L. (2013). Measuring the stance of monetary policy in zero lower bound environments. Economics Letters, 118(1), 135-138. Krippner, L. (2014). Measuring the stance of monetary policy in conventional and unconventional environments. Centre for Applied Macroeconomic Analysis, Crawford School of Public Policy, The Australian National University. Krippner, L. (2015a). A comment on Wu and Xia (2015), and the case for two-factor Shadow Short Rates. Centre for Applied Macroeconomic Analysis, Crawford School of Public Policy, The Australian National University. Krippner, L. (2015b). Zero lower bound term structure modeling: A practitioner’s guide. Springer. Krishnamurthy, A., & Vissing-Jorgensen, A. (2011). The effects of quantitative easing on interest rates: channels and implications for policy (No. w17555). National Bureau of Economic Research. Lombardi, M., & Zhu, F. (2014). A shadow policy rate to calibrate US monetary policy at the zero lower bound (No. 452). Bank for International Settlements. Miao, J. (2014). Economic dynamics in discrete time. MIT press. Smets, F., & Wouters, R. (2003). An estimated dynamic stochastic general equilibrium model of the euro area. Journal of the European economic association, 1(5), 1123-1175. Smets, F., & Wouters, R. (2007). Shocks and frictions in US business cycles: A Bayesian DSGE approach. American economic review, 97(3), 586-606. Walsh, C. E. (2017). Monetary theory and policy. MIT press. Wieland, J. F. (2015). Are negative supply shocks expansionary at the zero lower bound? Working Paper, University of California, San Diego. Wu, J. C., & Xia, F. D. (2016). Measuring the macroeconomic impact of monetary policy at the zero lower bound. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 48(2-3), 253-291. Wu, J. C., & Zhang, J. (2016). A shadow rate New Keynesian model (No. w22856). National Bureau of Economic Research Accepted 28 March 2019 Citation: Wang R (2019). A New Keynesian Model with Estimated Shadow Rate for Japan Economy. World Journal of Economics and Finance, 5(1): 106-114. Copyright: Β© 2019 Wang R. This is an open-access article distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution License, which permits unrestricted use, distribution, and reproduction in any medium, provided the original author and source are cited.