SlideShare a Scribd company logo
Secular Stagnation
Why Might Equilibrium Real Rates Have Fallen?
Increased Savings
Changes in distribution of income and profits share
Reserve accumulation or capital flight
Increasing deleveraging and retirement preparation
Decreases in Investment Propensity
Declining growth rate of population and/or technology
Demassification of the economy
Fall in price of capital goods
Other factors
Increased global save asset demand
3/14/2020 The Age of Secular Stagnation | Larry Summers
larrysummers.com/2016/02/17/the-age-of-secular-stagnation/
1/6
HOME CONTACT SEARCH
Lawrence H.
Summers is the
Charles W. Eliot
University Professor
and President
Emeritus at Harvard University. He
served as the 71st Secretary of the
Treasury for President Clinton and
the Director of the National Economic
Council for President Obama.
FULL BIO
Larry Summers on
SECULAR STAGNATION READ MORE
FOLLOW @LHSUMMERS
on Twitter
Larry Summers
COMMENTARY RESEARCH TEACHING MEDIA
RESOURCES
Summers published an article title, “The Age of Secular
Stagnation: What It Is and What to Do About It,” in the
February
issue of Foreign A�airs. The article explores how expansionary
�scal policy by the U.S. government can help overcome secular
stagnation problems and get growth back on track.
The Age of Secular Stagnation: What It Is and What to Do
About It
February 15, 2016
published in Foreign A�airs
As surprising as the recent �nancial crisis [1] and recession
were, the behavior of the
world’s industrialized economies and �nancial markets during
the recovery [2] has been
even more so.
Most observers expected the unusually deep recession to be
followed by an unusually
rapid recovery, with output and employment returning to trend
levels relatively quickly.
Yet even with the U.S. Federal Reserve [3]’s aggressive
monetary policies, the recovery
(both in the United States and around the globe) has fallen
signi�cantly short of
predictions and has been far weaker than its predecessors [4].
Had the American
economy performed as the Congressional Budget O�ce fore cast
in August 2009—after
the stimulus had been passed and the recovery had started—U.S.
GDP today would be
about $1.3 trillion higher than it is.
Almost no one in 2009 imagined that U.S. interest rates would
stay near zero for six
years, that key interest rates in Europe would turn negative, and
that central banks in the
G-7 would collectively expand their balance sheets by more
than $5 trillion. Had
economists been told such monetary policies lay ahead,
moreover, they would have
con�dently predicted that in�ation would become a serious
problem—and would have
been shocked to �nd out that across the United States, Europe,
and Japan, it has
generally remained well below two percent.
In the wake of the crisis, governments’ debt-to-GDP ratios have
risen sharply, from 41
percent in 2008 to 74 percent today in the United States, from
47 percent to 70 percent
in Europe, and from 95 percent to 126 percent in Japan. Yet
long-term interest rates are
still remarkably low, with ten-year government bond rates at
around two percent in the
United States, around 0.5 percent in Germany, and around 0.2
percent in Japan as of the
beginning of 2016. Such low long-term rates suggest that
markets currently expect both
low in�ation and low real interest rates to continue for many
years. With appropriate
caveats about the complexities of drawing inferences from
indexed bond markets, it is
fair to say that in�ation for the entire industrial world is
expected to be close to one
percent for another decade and that real interest rates are
expected to be around zero
over that time frame. In other words, nearly seven years into the
U.S. recovery, markets
are not expecting “normal” conditions to return anytime soon.
The key to understanding this situation lies in the concept of
secular stagnation [5], �rst
put forward by the economist Alvin Hansen in the 1930s. The
economies of the industrial
world, in this view, su�er from an imbalance resulting from an
increasing propensity to
save and a decreasing propensity to invest. The result is that
excessive saving acts as a
drag on demand, reducing growth and in�ation, and the
imbalance between savings and
investment pulls down real interest rates. When signi�cant
growth is achieved,
meanwhile—as in the United States between 2003 and 2007—it
comes from dangerous
levels of borrowing that translate excess savings into
unsustainable levels of investment
(which in this case emerged as a housing bubble).
Other explanations for what is happening have been proposed,
notably Kenneth Rogo�’s
theory of a debt overhang, Robert Gordon [6]’s theory of
supply-side headwinds, Ben
Bernanke’s theory of a savings glut [7], and Paul Krugman’s
theory of a liquidity trap. All
of these have some validity, but the secular stagnation theory
o�ers the most
The Age of Secular Stagnation
Print Email
258
36
http://larrysummers.com/
http://larrysummers.com/contact/
http://larrysummers.com/biography/
http://larrysummers.com/category/secular-stagnation/
http://larrysummers.com/category/secular-stagnation/
https://twitter.com/LHSummers
http://larrysummers.com/
http://larrysummers.com/commentary/
http://larrysummers.com/research/
http://larrysummers.com/teaching/
http://larrysummers.com/press-contacts/
https://www.foreignaffairs.com/reviews/2015-02-16/can-
economists-learn
https://www.foreignaffairs.com/reviews/review-essay/second-
great-depression
https://www.foreignaffairs.com/articles/united-states/2012-04-
23/all-presidents-central-bankers
https://www.foreignaffairs.com/articles/united-states/2011-06-
29/america-s-weak-recovery
http://www.economist.com/blogs/graphicdetail/2014/11/secular-
stagnation-graphics
https://www.foreignaffairs.com/reviews/review-essay/2016-01-
28/innovation-over
http://www.brookings.edu/blogs/ben-
bernanke/posts/2015/04/01-why-interest-rates-low-global-
savings-glut
http://larrysummers.com/2016/02/17/the-age-of-secular-
stagnation/?share=email&nb=1
3/14/2020 The Age of Secular Stagnation | Larry Summers
larrysummers.com/2016/02/17/the-age-of-secular-stagnation/
2/6
comprehensive account of the situation and the best basis for
policy prescriptions. The
good news is that although developments in China [8] and
elsewhere raise the risks that
global economic conditions will deteriorate, an expansionary
�scal policy by the U.S.
government can help overcome the secular stagnation problem
and get growth back on
track.
STUCK IN NEUTRAL
Just as the price of wheat adjusts to balance the supply of and
demand for wheat, it is
natural to suppose that interest rates—the price of money—
adjust to balance the supply
of savings and the demand for investment in an economy.
Excess savings tend to drive
interest rates down, and excess investment demand tends to
drive them up. Following
the Swedish economist Knut Wicksell, it is common to refer to
the real interest rate that
balances saving and investment at full employment as the
“natural,” or “neutral,” real
interest rate. Secular stagnation occurs when neutral real
interest rates are su�ciently
low that they cannot be achieved through conventional central-
bank policies. At that
point, desired levels of saving exceed desired levels of
investment, leading to shortfalls in
demand and stunted growth.
This picture �ts with much of what we have seen in recent
years. Real interest rates are
very low, demand has been sluggish, and in�ation is low, just
as one would expect in the
presence of excess saving. Absent many good new investment
opportunities, savings
have tended to �ow into existing assets, causing asset price
in�ation.
For secular stagnation to be a plausible hypothesis, there have
to be good reasons to
suppose that neutral real interest rates have been declining and
are now abnormally
low. And in fact, a number of recent studies have tried to look
at this question and have
generally found declines of several percentage points. Even
more convincing is the
increasing body of evidence suggesting that over the last
generation, various factors
have increased the propensity of populations in developed
countries to save and
reduced their propensity to invest. Greater saving has been
driven by increases in
inequality and in the share of income going to the wealthy,
increases in uncertainty
about the length of retirement and the availability of bene�ts,
reductions in the ability to
borrow (especially against housing), and a greater accumulation
of assets by foreign
central banks and sovereign wealth funds. Reduced investment
has been driven by
slower growth in the labor force, the availability of cheaper
capital goods, and tighter
credit (with lending more highly regulated than before).
Perhaps most important, the new economy [9] tends to conserve
capital. Apple and
Google, for example, are the two largest U.S. companies and are
eager to push the
frontiers of technology [10] forward, yet both are awash in cash
and are under pressure
to distribute more of it to their shareholders. Think about
Airbnb’s impact on hotel
construction, Uber’s impact on automobile demand, Amazon’s
impact on the
construction of malls, or the more general impact of information
technology on the
demand for copiers, printers, and o�ce space. And in a period
of rapid technological
change, it can make sense to defer investment lest new
technology soon make the old
obsolete.
Various studies have explored the impact of these factors and
attempted to estimate the
extent to which they have reduced neutral real interest rates.
The most recent and
thorough of these, by Lukasz Rachel and Thomas Smith at the
Bank of England,
concluded that for the industrial world, neutral real interest
rates have declined by about
4.5 percentage points over the last 30 years and are likely to
stay low in the future.
Together with the current price of long-term bonds, this
suggests that the kind of Japan-
style stagnation that has plagued the industrial world in recent
years may be with us for
quite some time.
DIFFERENTIAL DIAGNOSIS
Not all economists are sold on the secular stagnation
hypothesis. Building on the
monumental history of �nancial crises he wrote with Carmen
Reinhart, for example,
Rogo� ascribes current di�culties to excessive debt buildups
and subsequent
deleveraging. But although these surely contributed to the
�nancial crisis, they seem
insu�cient to account for the prolonged slow recovery.
Moreover, the debt buildups
theory provides no natural explanation for the generation-long
trend toward lower
neutral real interest rates. It seems more logical to see the debt
buildups decried by
Rogo� as not simply exogenous events but rather the
consequence of a growing excess
of saving over investment and the easy monetary policies
necessary to maintain full
employment.
https://www.foreignaffairs.com/articles/china/2016-01-11/end-
chinas-rise
https://www.foreignaffairs.com/articles/2015-12-12/fourth-
industrial-revolution
https://www.foreignaffairs.com/reviews/review-essay/thinkers-
and-tinkerers
3/14/2020 The Age of Secular Stagnation | Larry Summers
larrysummers.com/2016/02/17/the-age-of-secular-stagnation/
3/6
Gordon, meanwhile, has argued for what might be called
supply-side secular stagnation
—a fundamental decline in the rate of productivity growth
relative to its golden age,
from 1870 to 1970. Gordon is likely right that over the next
several years, the growth in
the potential output of the American economy and in the real
wages of American
workers will be quite slow. But if the primary culprit were
declining supply (as opposed
to declining demand), one would expect to see in�ation
accelerate rather than
decelerate.
For a decade, Bernanke has emphasized the idea of a savings
glut emanating from cash
thrown o� by emerging markets. This was indeed an important
factor in adding to
excess saving in the developed world a decade ago, and it may
well be again if emerging
markets continue to experience growing capital �ight. But both
the timing and the scale
of capital export from emerging markets make it unlikely that it
is the principal reason
for the major recent declines in neutral real interest rates.
Krugman and some others have sought to explain recent events
and make policy
recommendations based on the old Keynesian concept of
a liquidity trap [11]. As
Krugman has emphasized, this line of thinking is parallel to the
secular stagnation one.
But most treatments of the liquidity trap treat it as a temporary
phenomenon rather
than a potentially permanent state of a�airs, which is what the
evidence seems to be
showing.
Perhaps the most comforting alternative view is that secular
stagnation may have indeed
occurred in the past but is no longer operating in the present.
With the unemployment
rate down to �ve percent and the Fed embarked on a tightening
cycle, the argument
runs, indicators will start returning to earlier, higher growth
trends. Perhaps. But
markets are betting that the Fed will not be able to tighten
monetary policy nearly as
much as it expects, and if another recession starts in the next
few years, cuts will soon
bring interest rates back down to the zero lower bound.
LET’S GET FISCAL
Up to the 1970s, most economists believed that if governments
managed demand
properly, their countries’ economies could enjoy low
unemployment and high output
with relatively modest in�ation. The proper task of
macroeconomists, it followed, was to
use monetary and �scal policy to manage demand well. But this
thinking was eventually
challenged from two directions—in theory, by Milton
Friedman [12], Robert Lucas, and
others, and in practice, by the experience of high in�ation
together with high
unemployment.
The emergence of such “stag�ation” in the late 1970s [13] led
to general acceptance of
the natural-rate hypothesis, the idea that abnormally low
unemployment causes
in�ation to accelerate. According to this view, since
policymakers would not accept
permanently rising rates of in�ation, economies would tend to
�uctuate around a
natural rate of unemployment, determined by factors such as
labor �exibility, the
availability of bene�ts, and the e�ectiveness of hiring and job
searches. By skillfully
managing demand, policymakers could aspire to reduce the
amplitude of the
�uctuations—and although they could determine the average
rate of in�ation, they
could not raise the average level of output.
By the mid 1980s, once in�ation had been brought down from
double-digit levels, a
consensus on macroeconomic policy emerged. The central
objective of policy, most
mainstream economists believed, should be to achieve a low and
relatively stable rate of
in�ation, since there were no permanent gains to be had from
higher in�ation. This
could best be accomplished, it was thought, by �rmly
establishing the political
independence of central banks and by setting in�ation targets in
order to control
expectations. Fiscal policy, meanwhile, was not considered to
have a primary role in
managing demand, because it was slow acting and might push
interest rates up and
because monetary policy could do what was needed.
Seen through the lens of the secular stagnation hypothesis,
however, all these
propositions are problematic. If it were possible to avoid
secular stagnation, then it
would indeed be possible to increase average levels of output
substantially, raising the
stakes for demand management policy. The danger in monetary
policy, moreover, lies
not in politicians eager to in�ate away problems but in bankers
refusing to generate
enough demand to bring in�ation up to target levels and permit
reductions in real
interest rates. And �scal policy, �nally, takes on new
signi�cance as a tool in economic
stabilization.
http://krugman.blogs.nytimes.com/2013/04/11/monetary-policy-
in-a-liquidity-trap/?_r=0
https://www.foreignaffairs.com/reviews/capsule-review/2007-
05-01/milton-friedman-biography
https://www.foreignaffairs.com/articles/united-states/1979-09-
01/stagflation-how-we-got-it-how-get-out
3/14/2020 The Age of Secular Stagnation | Larry Summers
larrysummers.com/2016/02/17/the-age-of-secular-stagnation/
4/6
As of yet, none of these principles has been fully accepted by
policymakers in the
advanced industrial world. It is true that central banks have
sought, through quantitative
easing, to loosen monetary conditions even with short-term
interest rates at rock
bottom. But they have treated these policies as a short-term
expedient, not a longer-
term necessity. More important, these policies are running into
diminishing returns and
giving rise to increasingly toxic side e�ects. Sustained low
rates tend to promote excess
leverage, risk taking, and asset bubbles.
This does not mean that quantitative easing was mistaken.
Without such policies, output
would likely be even lower, and the world economy might well
have tipped into de�ation.
But monetary-policy makers need to acknowledge much more
explicitly that neutral real
rates have fallen substantially and that the task now is to adjust
policy accordingly. This
could include setting targets for nominal GDP growth rather
than in�ation, investing in a
wider range of risk assets, making plans to allow base rates to
turn negative, and
underscoring the importance of avoiding a new recession.
When the primary policy challenge for central banks was
establishing credibility that the
printing press was under control, it was appropriate for them to
jealously guard their
independence. When the challenge is to accelerate, rather than
brake, economies, more
cooperation with domestic �scal authorities and foreign
counterparts is necessary.
The core problem of secular stagnation is that the neutral real
interest rate is too low.
This rate, however, cannot be increased through monetary
policy. Indeed, to the extent
that easy money works by accelerating investments and pulling
forward demand, it will
actually reduce neutral real rates later on. That is why primary
responsibility for
addressing secular stagnation should rest with �scal policy. An
expansionary �scal policy
can reduce national savings, raise neutral real interest rates, and
stimulate growth.
Fiscal policy has other virtues as well, particularly when
pursued through public
investment. A time of low real interest rates, low materials
prices, and high construction
unemployment is the ideal moment for a large public investment
program. It is tragic,
therefore, that in the United States today, federal infrastructure
investment, net of
depreciation, is running close to zero, and net government
investment is lower than at
any time in nearly six decades.
It is true that an expansionary �scal policy would increase
de�cits, and many worry that
running larger de�cits would place larger burdens on later
generations, who will already
face the challenges of an aging society. But those future
generations will be better o�
owing lots of money in long-term bonds at low rates in a
currency they can print than
they would be inheriting a vast deferred maintenance liability.
Traditional concern with �scal de�cits has focused on their
impact in pushing up interest
rates and retarding investment. Yet by setting yields so low and
bond prices so high,
markets are sending a clear signal that they want more, not less,
government debt. By
stimulating growth and enabling an in�ation increase that
would permit a reduction in
real capital costs, �scal expansion now would crowd investment
in rather than out. Well-
intentioned proposals to curtail prospective pension bene�ts, in
contrast, might make
matters even worse by encouraging increased saving and
reduced consumption, thus
exacerbating secular stagnation.
The main constraint on the industrial world’s economy today is
on the demand, rather
than the supply, side. This means that measures that increase
potential supply by
promoting �exibility are therefore less important than measures
that o�er the potential
to increase demand, such as regulatory reform and business tax
reform. Other structural
policies that would promote demand include steps to accelerate
investments in
renewable technologies that could replace fossil fuels and
measures to raise the share of
total income going to those with a high propensity to consume,
such as support for
unions and increased minimum wages. Thus, John Maynard
Keynes, writing in a similar
situation during the late 1930s, rightly emphasized the need for
policy approaches that
both promoted business con�dence—the cheapest form of
stimulus—and increased
labor compensation.
TO HANGZHOU AND BEYOND
If each of the countries facing secular stagnation today were to
confront it successfully
on its own, the results would be very favorable for the global
economy. But international
focus and coordination have crucial additional roles to play.
Secular stagnation, after all, increases the contagion from
economic weakness. In normal
times, if the rest of the world economy su�ers, the United
States or any other a�ected
3/14/2020 The Age of Secular Stagnation | Larry Summers
larrysummers.com/2016/02/17/the-age-of-secular-stagnation/
5/6
economy can o�set the loss of demand and competitiveness
through monetary easing.
With monetary policy already at its lower limit, however,
additional easing is impossible
(or at least much more di�cult), and so each country’s stake in
the strength of the global
economy is greatly magni�ed.
Secular stagnation also increases the danger of competitive
monetary easing and even
of currency wars. Looser money, starting with near-zero capital
costs, is likely to
generate demand primarily through increases in
competitiveness. This is a zero-sum
game, since currency movements switch demand from one
country to another rather
than increase it globally. Fiscal expansions, in contrast, raise
demand on a global basis.
International coordination is thus necessary to avoid an
excessive and self-defeating
reliance on monetary policy and achieve a mutually rewarding
reliance on �scal policy to
address problems.
Movements in commodity prices in recent months have shown
that events in emerging
markets, especially China, can have signi�cant impacts
globally. It now appears likely that
more capital will �ow out of emerging markets and less will
�ow in than has been the
case in recent years. These capital out�ows and the consequent
increases in net exports
will further reduce demand and neutral real rates in the
developed world, thereby
exacerbating secular stagnation. Policies that help restore
con�dence in emerging
markets, therefore, will also strengthen the global economy.
These issues were recognized at the successful G-20 summit in
London in April 2009
(although the problems were misdiagnosed as cyclical and
temporary rather than
secular and enduring). The common commitments undertaken
there to engage in �scal
expansion, strengthen �nancial regulation, resist trade
protection, and enhance the
capacity of international �nancial institutions to respond to
problems in emerging
markets were e�ective in halting the collapse of the global
economy. Unfortunately,
subsequent G-20 summits returned to their traditional lethargy
and misguided
preoccupation with �scal austerity, monetary normalization,
and moral hazard, ending
up missing opportunities to accelerate the recovery.
This year, the Chinese will host a G-20 summit in September. If
China chooses to
recognize how important global growth is for its economy, and
how important its
economy is for global growth, it could perform a great service
by reinvigorating
international economic cooperation. The key priority in
Hangzhou—as it was in London
back in 2009—should be increasing global demand and making
sure that it picks up
particularly in those countries where there is the most economic
slack.
In this regard, China’s decisions about its own economic a�airs
will be crucial. To date,
the international community has joined Chinese �nancial
o�cials in urging China’s
political leadership to pursue �nancial liberalization. This is
surely correct for the long
run. But it may well be in China’s and the global interest that
the liberalization process
proceed more gradually than is currently envisioned, so that
capital out�ows from China
do not threaten China’s own �nancial stability and spread
weakness to the global
economy at large.
As the euro has declined sharply, meanwhile, any recovery that
Europe has achieved has
come largely from increases in competitiveness that reduce
growth elsewhere. Germany
now leads the world with a trade surplus equal to a whopping
eight percent of GDP. The
global community should encourage Europe to generate
domestic demand as it seeks to
expand its economy.
One more priority in Hangzhou should be promoting global
infrastructure investment. In
this regard, the Chinese-led Asian Infrastructure Investment
Bank [14] is a valuable step
forward, and it should be strongly supported by the global
community, even as it is
encouraged to respect international norms and standards relating
to issues such as
environmental protection and integrity in procurement. And
e�orts to support
infrastructure investment elsewhere, such as the Obama
administration’s Power Africa
initiative, should be carried forward.
Secular stagnation and the slow growth and �nancial instability
associated with it have
political as well as economic consequences. If middle-class
living standards were
increasing at traditional rates, politics across the developed
world would likely be far
less surly and dysfunctional. So mitigating secular stagnation is
of profound importance.
Writing in 1930, in circumstances far more dire than those we
face today, Keynes still
managed to summon some optimism. Using a British term for a
type of alternator in a
car engine, he noted that the economy had what he called
“magneto trouble.” A car with
a broken alternator won’t move at all—yet it takes only a simple
repair to get it going. In
https://www.foreignaffairs.com/articles/china/2015-05-07/whos-
afraid-aiib
3/14/2020 The Age of Secular Stagnation | Larry Summers
larrysummers.com/2016/02/17/the-age-of-secular-stagnation/
6/6
© LAWRENCE H. SUMMERS, 2019
much the same way, secular stagnation does not reveal a
profound or inherent �aw in
capitalism. Raising demand is actually not that di�cult, and it is
much easier than raising
the capacity to produce. The crucial thing is for policymakers to
diagnose the problem
correctly and make the appropriate repairs.
Copyright © 2016 by the Council on Foreign Relations, Inc.
All rights reserved. To request permission to distribute or
reprint this article, please �ll
out and submit a Permissions Request Form. If you plan to use
this article in a
coursepack or academic website, visit Copyright Clearance
Center to clear permission.
Source URL: https://www.foreigna�airs.com/articles/united-
states/2016-02-15/age-
secular-stagnation
Links
[1] https://www.foreigna�airs.com/reviews/2015-02-16/can-
economists-learn
[2] https://www.foreigna�airs.com/reviews/review-
essay/second-great-depression
[3] https://www.foreigna�airs.com/articles/united-states/2012-
04-23/all-presidents-
central-bankers
[4] https://www.foreigna�airs.com/articles/united-states/2011-
06-29/america-s-weak-
recovery
[5]
http://www.economist.com/blogs/graphicdetail/2014/11/secular-
stagnation-graphics
[6] https://www.foreigna�airs.com/reviews/review-essay/2016-
01-28/innovation-over
[7] http://www.brookings.edu/blogs/ben-
bernanke/posts/2015/04/01-why-interest-rates-
low-global-savings-glut
[8] https://www.foreigna�airs.com/articles/china/2016-01-
11/end-chinas-rise
[9] https://www.foreigna�airs.com/articles/2015-12-12/fourth-
industrial-revolution
[10] https://www.foreigna�airs.com/reviews/review-
essay/thinkers-and-tinkerers
[11] http://krugman.blogs.nytimes.com/2013/04/11/monetary-
policy-in-a-liquidity-trap/?
_r=0
[12] https://www.foreigna�airs.com/reviews/capsule-
review/2007-05-01/milton-
friedman-biography
[13] https://www.foreigna�airs.com/articles/united-states/1979-
09-01/stag�ation-how-
we-got-it-how-get-out
[14] https://www.foreigna�airs.com/articles/china/2015-05-
07/whos-afraid-aiib
https://www.youtube.com/channel/UCF_dVFHJjSCiUJVZdf7Hlf
Q
https://www.facebook.com/LarrySummers/
https://twitter.com/LHSummers
http://www.foreignaffairs.com/permissions
http://www.copyright.com/
https://www.foreignaffairs.com/articles/united-states/2016-02-
15/age-secular-stagnation
https://www.foreignaffairs.com/reviews/2015-02-16/can-
economists-learn
https://www.foreignaffairs.com/reviews/review-essay/second-
great-depression
https://www.foreignaffairs.com/articles/united-states/2012-04-
23/all-presidents-central-bankers
https://www.foreignaffairs.com/articles/united-states/2011-06-
29/america-s-weak-recovery
http://www.economist.com/blogs/graphicdetail/2014/11/secular-
stagnation-graphics
https://www.foreignaffairs.com/reviews/review-essay/2016-01-
28/innovation-over
…
1/22/2018 The Great Recession: A Macroeconomic Earthquake |
Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis
https://minneapolisfed.org/research/economic-policy-
papers/the-great-recession-a-macroeconomic-earthquake 1/8
HOME CAREERS CONTACT Search
Home > Economic Research > Economic Policy Papers > The
Great Recession: A Macroeconomic Earthquake
Economic Policy Papers RSS
PDF Version TWEET SHARE POST EMAIL PRINT
The Great Recession: A Macroeconomic
Earthquake
Why it happened, endured and wasn’t foreseen. And how it’s
changing theory
Lawrence J. Christiano | Consultant
Published February 7, 2017
Economic Policy Papers are based on policy-oriented research
produced by Minneapolis Fed staff and consultants. The
papers are an occasional series for a general audience. The
views expressed here are those of the authors, not necessarily
those of others in the Federal Reserve System.
Executive Summary
The Great Recession was particularly severe and has endured
far
longer than most recessions. Economists now believe it was
caused by a perfect storm of declining home prices, a financial
system heavily invested in house-related assets and a shadow
banking system highly vulnerable to bank runs or rollover risk.
It
has lasted longer than most recessions because economically
damaged households were unwilling or unable to increase
spending, thus perpetuating the recession by a mechanism
known
as the paradox of thrift. Economists believe the Great Recession
wasn’t foreseen because the size and fragility of the shadow
banking system had gone unnoticed.
The recession has had an inordinate impact on macroeconomics
as a discipline, leading economists to reconsider two largely
discarded theories: IS-LM and the paradox of thrift. It has also
forced theorists to better understand and incorporate the
financial
sector into their models, the most promising of which focus on
mismatch between the maturity periods of assets and liabilities
held by banks.
Introduction
Latest Content from
the Minneapolis Fed
Minneapolis Fed Releases Report on
Early Childhood Development in
Montana
News Releases
Slow Convergence in Economies with
Organization Capital
Working Paper
Early Childhood Development in
Montana
Community Development Papers
WSJ Op-Ed: Immigration Is Practically a
Free Lunch for America
Messages
Equity and Efficiency in Space
The Region
Connect
MinneapolisFed on Twitter
Minneapolis Fed on Facebook
RSS Feeds
About the Fed Banking Supervision Economic Research
Regional Economy Community & Education News & Events
Publications
https://minneapolisfed.org/
https://minneapolisfed.org/
https://minneapolisfed.org/about/careers
https://minneapolisfed.org/forms/contact
https://minneapolisfed.org/
https://minneapolisfed.org/research
https://minneapolisfed.org/research/economic-policy-papers
https://minneapolisfed.org/research/economic-policy-papers
https://minneapolisfed.org/research/economic-policy-papers/rss
https://minneapolisfed.org/research/economic-policy-papers/rss
https://minneapolisfed.org/~/media/files/pubs/eppapers/17-
1/the-great-recession-a-macroeconomic-earthquake.pdf
javascript:window.print()
https://minneapolisfed.org/research/economic-policy-papers
https://minneapolisfed.org/authors/lawrence-j-christiano
https://minneapolisfed.org/research/economic-policy-papers
https://minneapolisfed.org/news-and-events/news-
releases/minneapolis-fed-releases-report-on-early-childhood-
development-in-montana
https://minneapolisfed.org/research/working-papers/slow-
convergence-in-economies-with-organization-capital
https://minneapolisfed.org/community/community-development-
papers/early-childhood-development-in-montana
https://minneapolisfed.org/news-and-events/messages/wsj-op-
ed-immigration-is-practically-a-free-lunch-for-america
https://minneapolisfed.org/publications/the-region/equity-and-
efficiency-in-space
http://www.twitter.com/minneapolisfed
http://www.facebook.com/MinneapolisFed
https://minneapolisfed.org/publications/subscriptions-rss-and-
reader/rss
https://minneapolisfed.org/about
https://minneapolisfed.org/banking
https://minneapolisfed.org/research
https://minneapolisfed.org/economy
https://minneapolisfed.org/community
https://minneapolisfed.org/news-and-events
https://minneapolisfed.org/publications
1/22/2018 The Great Recession: A Macroeconomic Earthquake |
Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis
https://minneapolisfed.org/research/economic-policy-
papers/the-great-recession-a-macroeconomic-earthquake 2/8
The Great Recession struck individuals, the aggregate economy
and the economics profession like an earthquake, and its
aftershocks are still being felt. Job losses and housing
foreclosures devastated many families. National economies
were
deeply damaged and have yet to fully recover. And
economists—
who failed to predict either the crisis or the recession— have
been
struggling to understand why they didn’t grasp the fragility of
the
financial system and the duration of the recession.
This essay briefly discusses why the Great Recession is
considered both “Great” and a “Recession.” It then turns to the
emerging consensus about its cause, its duration and the reasons
so few predicted it. Finally, it explores the impact of the Great
Recession on how academic economists now think about the
economy.
“Great Recession”
The economic downturn the United States suffered from late
2007
to the third quarter of 2009 was particularly damaging. Output,
consumption, investment, employment and total hours worked
dropped far more during the recent recession than the
comparable average figures for all other recessions since 1945.
Employment, for example, dropped 6.7 percent during the 2007-
09 recession compared with an average of 3.8 percent for
postwar recessions. Analogous figures for output: 7.2 percent
and
4.4 percent; for consumption: 5.4 percent and 2.1 percent. That
higher level of severity across the board is why this recession
has
earned the adjective “Great.”
By the same token, however, this recession was definitely not
the
worst U.S. downturn on record. Conditions were far worse
during
the Great Depression. Employment fell 27 percent from 1929 to
1933 (compared with 6.7 percent from 2007 to 2009), output
fell
36 percent (7.2 percent) and consumption fell 23 percent (5.4
percent). For that reason, the recent slump, though severe, is
rightly considered a recession rather than a full-bore depression.
Another reason to consider this recession “Great” is how
uncommonly long the economy has been taking to recover. The
accompanying figure displays labor productivity (output per
working-age person, adjusted for inflation) from 1977 through
2014. The vertical pink bars in the figure indicate the starting
and
ending dates for recessions, as determined by the National
Bureau of Economic Research (NBER).
1
1/22/2018 The Great Recession: A Macroeconomic Earthquake |
Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis
https://minneapolisfed.org/research/economic-policy-
papers/the-great-recession-a-macroeconomic-earthquake 3/8
The U.S. economy did not return to the 2007 level of output per
capita until a little over five years later, in first quarter 2013.
The
productivity trend lines for the previous four recessions show
that
the economy usually snaps back more quickly. Even now, the
U.S. economy is still about 10 percent below normal (that is,
trend
growth in 2007).
What caused the Great Recession?
Conventional wisdom is now converging on a particular
narrative
about the cause of the Great Recession. In effect, the Great
Recession was a “perfect storm” created by the concurrence of
three factors. Taken by itself, none of these factors would have
caused a major recession, but in combination, they were
explosive.
The first was the decline in housing prices that began in the
summer of 2007. Whether this was the end of a “bubble” or just
an ordinary fluctuation does not matter for the narrative. The
second factor was that the financial system was heavily invested
in housing-related assets, mortgage-backed securities. The third
factor was that the shadow banking system was invested in
housing assets and highly vulnerable to bank runs.
These three factors are the essential elements in the following
narrative about the Great Recession.
The fall in housing prices damaged the assets of the shadow
banking system and thereby created the conditions in which a
run
on the shadow banking system could occur. Alas, a run did
occur
in the summer of 2007, forcing the shadow banking system to
sell
its assets at fire sale prices.
This asset decline damaged the whole banking system and
hindered its ability to intermediate not just house purchases, but
investment more generally. With reduced credit, purchases of
houses declined and the fall in house prices was reinforced.
By reducing household wealth, the fall in house prices induced
households to cut back on spending. Faced with declining sales,
firms pulled back on investment and hiring. All of these factors
reinforced each other, sending the economy into the tailspin
documented above.
2
3
4
5
6
1/22/2018 The Great Recession: A Macroeconomic Earthquake |
Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis
https://minneapolisfed.org/research/economic-policy-
papers/the-great-recession-a-macroeconomic-earthquake 4/8
Why has it lasted so long?
The conventional view on why the recession lasted so long is
that
the events described in the previous paragraph reinforced the
desire to save, relative to the desire to invest. If markets worked
efficiently, then the interest rate would have fallen to balance
the
demand and supply of savings, without a significant fall in
employment. According to the conventional view, this required
that interest rates be substantially negative, something that
could
not be achieved because the nominal interest rate cannot be
much below zero. Because interest rates could not fall enough
to
clear lending markets, something else had to bring the demand
and supply of saving into equality. That something else was the
fall in aggregate output and income, which allowed lending
markets to clear by reducing saving as people tried to avoid
reducing their consumption too much. This is essentially the
logic
of the “paradox of thrift” analyzed in undergraduate textbooks
in
macroeconomics. Consistent with those textbooks, the fall in
output arising from this paradox-of-thrift reasoning could in
principle last for a long time.
Why didn’t policymakers or economists see it coming?
The emerging consensus is that no one, neither policymakers
nor
academic economists, was aware of the third factor underlying
the
Great Recession, the size and fragility of the shadow banking
sector (see, for example, Bernanke 2010). The reason is simple.
Much of what policymakers and economists know about
financial
markets comes about as a side effect of regulation, and the
shadow banking system existed mostly outside the normal
regulatory framework.
Impact on macroeconomics
The Great Recession is having an enormous impact on
macroeconomics as a discipline, in two ways. First, it is leading
economists to reconsider two theories that had largely been
discredited or neglected. Second, it has led the profession to
find
ways to incorporate the financial sector into macroeconomic
theory.
Neglected paradigms
At its heart, the narrative described above characterizes the
Great
Recession as the response of the economy to a negative shock to
the demand for goods all across the board. This is very much in
the spirit of the traditional macroeconomic paradigm captured
by
the famous IS-LM (or Hicks-Hansen) model, which places
demand shocks like this at the heart of its theory of business
cycle
fluctuations. Similarly, the paradox-of-thrift argument is also
expressed naturally in the IS-LM model.
The IS-LM paradigm, together with the paradox of thrift and the
notion that a decision by a group of people could give rise to a
welfare-reducing drop in output, had been largely discredited
among professional macroeconomists since the 1980s. But the
Great Recession seems impossible to understand without
invoking paradox-of-thrift logic and appealing to shocks in
aggregate demand. As a consequence, the modern equivalent of
the IS-LM model—the New Keynesian model—has returned to
center stage. (To be fair, the return of the IS-LM model began
in
7
8
9
10
11
12
1/22/2018 The Great Recession: A Macroeconomic Earthquake |
Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis
https://minneapolisfed.org/research/economic-policy-
papers/the-great-recession-a-macroeconomic-earthquake 5/8
the late 1990s, but the Great Recession dramatically accelerated
the process.)
The return of the dynamic version of the IS-LM model is
revolutionary because that model is closely allied with the view
that the economic system can sometimes become dysfunctional,
necessitating some form of government intervention. This is a
big
shift from the dominant view in the macroeconomics profession
in
the wake of the costly high inflation of the 1970s. Because that
inflation was viewed as a failure of policy, many economists in
the
1980s were comfortable with models that imply markets work
well
by themselves and government intervention is typically
unproductive.
Accounting for the financial sector
The Great Recession has had a second important effect on the
practice of macroeconomics. Before the Great Recession, there
was a consensus among professional macroeconomists that
dysfunction in the financial sector could safely be ignored by
macroeconomic theory. The idea was that what happens on Wall
Street stays on Wall Street—that is, it has as little impact on the
economy as what happens in Las Vegas casinos. This idea
received support from the U.S. experiences in 1987 and the
early
2000s, when the economy seemed unfazed by substantial stock
market volatility. But the idea that financial markets could be
ignored in macroeconomics died with the Great Recession.
Now macroeconomists are actively thinking about the financial
system, how it interacts with the broader economy and how it
should be regulated. This has necessitated the construction of
new models that incorporate finance, and the models that are
empirically successful have generally integrated financial
factors
into a version of the New Keynesian model, for the reasons
discussed above. (See, for example, Christiano, Motto and
Rostagno 2014.)
Economists have made much progress in this direction, too
much
to summarize in this brief essay. One particularly notable set of
advances is seen in recent research by Mark Gertler, Nobuhiro
Kiyotaki and Andrea Prestipino. (See Gertler and Kiyotaki 2015
and Gertler, Kiyotaki and Prestipino 2016.) In their models,
banks
finance long-term assets with short-term liabilities. This
liquidity
mismatch between assets and liabilities captures the essential
reason that real world financial institutions are vulnerable to
runs.
As such, the model enables economists to think precisely about
the narrative described above (and advocated by Bernanke 2010
and others) about what launched the Great Recession in 2007.
Refining models of this kind is essential for understanding the
root
causes of severe economic downturns and for designing
regulatory and other policies that can prevent a recurrence of
disasters like the Great Recession.
Endnotes
1 The output and population data were obtained from FRED, the
online database maintained by the Federal Reserve Bank of St.
Louis. The FRED label for the output measure is GDPC1, and
the
label for the working-age population is LFWA64TTUSQ647S.
1/22/2018 The Great Recession: A Macroeconomic Earthquake |
Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis
https://minneapolisfed.org/research/economic-policy-
papers/the-great-recession-a-macroeconomic-earthquake 6/8
2 The exact amount of time required for per capita output to
return
to its prerecession peak depends somewhat on the population
measure used. If instead the civilian non-institutional
population
measure (FRED label CNP16OV) were used, then the amount of
time would have been longer, roughly seven years. The
difference
from the results in the figure reflects demographic factors that
cause the working-age population to grow less rapidly than the
population as a whole.
3 For additional discussion about the trend of U.S. economic
output in 2007, see Christiano, Eichenbaum and Trabandt
(2015).
The 10 percent number in the text was rounded after doing the
following calculations. I fit a linear time trend to the natural
logarithm of the output measure in the figure, using data from
the
beginning of the sample to the fourth quarter of 2007, the
quarter
before the Great Recession began according to the NBER. I
extended the trend to the end of the sample. The difference
between the trend at the end of the sample and the (log of the)
last data point is 0.136, which I rounded to 0.10. The 10 percent
number reported in the text is the last number, multiplied by
100.
4 An early, subsequently discarded, view was the so-called
labor
mismatch hypothesis. It held that the low level of employment
was
not due to a lack of jobs, but to the lack of workers with the
right
skills to fill them. Workforce and firms were “mismatched.”
This view lost its appeal as it became apparent just how broad-
based the recession was. Employment and hours worked fell in
virtually all sectors. The unemployment rate jumped for
virtually
every type of worker, by level of education and occupation.
According to the mismatch hypothesis, wage growth should
have
been especially high and unemployment low for the highly
sought-
after types of workers. But jobs were scarce virtually
everywhere,
for everyone.
Why did employers hire so few workers? Since the early 1970s,
the National Federation of Independent Business has surveyed
its
members to find out what their top problem is. They are asked
to
select from among 10 possibilities, including taxes, inflation,
poor
sales and quality of labor. Under the mismatch hypothesis, a
large
fraction of firms should have selected “quality of labor” as their
top
problem. They didn’t. Instead, “poor sales” surged beyond all
other options as their top problem. Firms were not hiring simply
because people were not buying their goods and services.
5 It is an interesting story, beyond the scope of this analysis,
how
so much money came to be invested in mortgages. Under the
conventional view, the source of the money was what Bernanke
(2005) called the “savings glut”: Money poured in from high-
saving countries in Asia and oil-producing regions. Under what
Shin (2012) called the “banking glut,” a lot of that incoming
money
went to Europe and then came right back to the United States.
The European institutions that managed this back-and-forth
flow
had a strong preference for mortgages.
Evidence in favor of the notion that the large current account
deficit reflected an increase in the supply of funds by foreigners
is
the sharp drop in interest rates since 2000. The evidence that a
lot of the extra money went into mortgages is that mortgage
rates
and lending conditions became particularly loose. For further
discussion of this view, see Justiniano, Primiceri and
Tambalotti
1/22/2018 The Great Recession: A Macroeconomic Earthquake |
Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis
https://minneapolisfed.org/research/economic-policy-
papers/the-great-recession-a-macroeconomic-earthquake 7/8
(2015). Evidence consistent with the notion that the U.S.
current
account deficit played an important role in housing markets can
also be seen in the substantial covariation between U.S. housing
prices and the current account (see Figure 1.1 in Justiano,
Primiceri and Tambalotti 2015).
6 Technically, what happened was a rollover crisis, not a
traditional bank run like those familiar from movies and
photographs from the Great Depression. For a careful discussion
of a rollover crisis, see Gertler and Kiyotaki (2015).
7 The paradox-of-thrift argument described in the text lies at
the
heart of the analysis of the interest rate lower bound in
Eggertsson and Woodford (2003).
8 That shadow banking system was of a similar order of
magnitude as the traditional banking system discussed in
Geithner (2008).
9 The IS-LM model—often depicted graphically and thought to
encapsulate traditional Keynesian theory—describes the
relationship between real output (GDP) and nominal interest
rates. On a graph with real interest rates on the vertical axis and
real GDP on the horizontal, IS-LM is seen as a downward-
sloping
IS curve (investment and savings, or the market for economic
goods) and an upward-sloping LM curve (liquidity preference
and
money supply). The intersection of these curves indicates an
economy’s equilibrium interest rate and GDP.
10 This is the idea that if people feel poor because the economy
is not prospering, they’ll cut back on spending; that cutback
will, in
turn, encourage businesses to retrench on investment and hiring,
leading to a self-fulfilling prophecy of economic downturn. The
“paradox” is that while thrift at the individual level may be
wise, it
can have a harmful impact on the broader economy and
ultimately
on individuals as well. See, for example, “Paradox” Redux in
the
June 2013 Region.
11 Businesses reducing investment when they experience lower
sales, for instance, or households cutting back because they feel
poor with the fall in house prices.
12 For another model that may also be able to come to terms
with
the data on the Great Recession, see Buera and Nicolini (2016).
References
Bernanke, Ben S. 2005. “The Global Saving Glut and the U.S.
Current Account Deficit.” Sandridge Lecture. Virginia
Association
of Economists, April 14.
Bernanke, Ben S. 2010. Statement before the Financial Crisis
Inquiry Commission. Washington, D.C., Sept. 2.
https://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/testimony/bernanke
20100902a.pdf
Buera, Francisco and Juan Pablo Nicolini. 2016. “Liquidity
Traps
and Monetary Policy: Managing a Credit Crunch.” Unpublished
manuscript, Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago.
Christiano, Lawrence J., Martin S. Eichenbaum and Mathias
Trabandt. 2015. “Understanding the Great Recession.”
American
Economic Journal: Macroeconomics 7 (1): 110-67.
https://minneapolisfed.org/publications/the-region/paradox-
redux
https://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/testimony/bernanke
20100902a.pdf
1/22/2018 It Wasn't Household Debt That Caused the Great
Recession - The Atlantic
https://www.theatlantic.com/business/archive/2014/05/house-of-
debt/371282/ 1/10
Like The Atlantic? Subscribe to The Atlantic Daily , our free
weekday email newsletter.
Email SIGN UP
Why are nearly 10 million people still out of work today? Was
it because in
September 2008, the U.S. government failed to bail out the
insolvent investment
bank Lehmann Brothers? Was it because the two U.S. housing
finance giants
Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac guaranteed too many mortgages
securitized by
It Wasn't Household Debt That Caused the Great
Recession
It was how that debt was disproportionately distributed to
America’s most
economically fragile communities.
HEATHER BOUSHEY
MAY 21, 2014 | BUSINESS
Reuters
http://www.theatlantic.com/newsletters/daily/
https://www.theatlantic.com/author/heather-boushey/
https://www.theatlantic.com/business/
1/22/2018 It Wasn't Household Debt That Caused the Great
Recession - The Atlantic
https://www.theatlantic.com/business/archive/2014/05/house-of-
debt/371282/ 2/10
Lehman and other Wall Street firms to low-income borrowers in
the run up to the
housing and financial crises? Or does blame rest with the
Federal Reserve’s too-
easy-money policies in the wake of the brief dotcom recession
in the early 2000s?
Princeton University professor Atif Mian and University of
Chicago Booth School of
Business professor Amir Sufi pin the blame squarely on
policymakers, but not for
any of these three reasons, all of which are variously popular
with policymakers on
different sides of the political divide in Washington. Instead, in
their just-released
book, House of Debt, they argue that the Great Recession was
the result of a sharp
fall-off in consumption due to the unevenly accumulated
household debt in the first
six years of the 21st century. In that period, mortgage-credit
grew more than twice
as fast in neighborhoods with low credit scores than in
neighborhoods with high
credit scores, a marked departure from the experience of
previous decades. When
the housing bubble popped, the economic consequences were
sharply magnified by
the way debt was distributed across households and
communities.
How did this happen? Why did lenders suddenly shower less-
creditworthy
borrowers with trillions of dollars of credit? Mian and Sufi
demonstrate this was
enabled by the securitization of home mortgages by investment
banks that did not
seek federal guarantees from Fannie and Freddie—so called
private-label
securities, made possible by financial deregulation and the glut
of cash in world
markets in the wake of the Asian financial crisis of the late
1990s. That private-
label mortgage-backed securities were at the core of the housing
meltdown is no
longer in doubt, but what Mian and Sufi bring to the debate is
how an unequal
distribution of debt magnified the economic risks—based on
their path-breaking
microeconomic research—and a new framework for considering
who is to blame
among policymakers for the still reverberating debacle.
Unfortunately, the two authors don’t provide answers for why
so many households
took on so much debt, but they do paint a cautionary tale. This
is a critically
important contribution to the policy debate now raging over
what Congress and the
Obama administration should do in the way of reforms to the
housing-finance
industry. And, it’s important to our understanding of whether
and how inequality
http://www.amazon.com/House-Debt-Recession-Prevent-
Happening/dp/022608194X
1/22/2018 It Wasn't Household Debt That Caused the Great
Recession - The Atlantic
https://www.theatlantic.com/business/archive/2014/05/house-of-
debt/371282/ 3/10
affects economic growth and stability. What they demonstrate is
that as the U.S.
housing bubble burst and home prices began to fall in late 2006,
the unequal
distribution of debt amplified the decline in consumer spending
and the
consequence was an economic disaster. Mian and Sufi’s
research leads them to
conclude that the crisis was avoidable if only economists had
used the right
framework to see what was happening around them at the time.
“Economic disasters are man-made,” they write in the opening
pages, “and the
right framework can help us understand how to prevent them.”
By the end of the
book, the reader cannot but be left appalled at the sheer
enormity of the policy
failures. It’s not just that 7.4 million workers lost their job
during the years of the
Great Recession of 2007-2009 but also that the employment
crisis continues to
this day. While jobs are no longer being shed at the rate of
20,000 a day, the share
of the U.S. population with a job fell to a low of 58.2 percent in
November 2010
from a high of 63.4 percent in December 2006, but has only
increased by a fraction
of a percentage since then, hitting just 58.9 percent in April
2014.
Missing the housing bubble was a massive failure on the part of
policymakers. As a
result, our new normal is one where there are nearly 10 million
fewer people at
work. This book's contribution helps us understand the
important mechanisms
through which this occurred.
* * *
I watched the housing and financial crises unfold from my perch
as staff for the U.S.
Congressional Joint Economic Committee. By the time Lehman
Brothers failed, the
mantra on Capitol Hill had been articulated by former Treasury
Secretary Lawrence Summers, who said that any recovery
package had to be
“timely, targeted, and temporary.” But the stimulus that
emerged was not
specifically targeted at homeowners in foreclosure. If Mian and
Sufi are correct, the
biggest failure was—and continues to be—leaving families
struggling with
mortgages they cannot afford because of the fall in home prices.
http://www.nytimes.com/roomfordebate/2014/05/20/did-the-
bank-bailout-do-enough-for-the-country
1/22/2018 It Wasn't Household Debt That Caused the Great
Recession - The Atlantic
https://www.theatlantic.com/business/archive/2014/05/house-of-
debt/371282/ 4/10
The federal government has provided assistance to a paltry
940,000 struggling
homeowners through the Homeowners Assistance Mortgage
Program, in a nation
where 5 million homes have been foreclosed on. This lack of
help hasn’t just hurt
those homeowners. Also caught in the downdraft are now
destroyed
neighborhoods, ruined communities, and thwarted lives of far
too many.
Protecting banks does not necessarily make the economy strong.
So, how did we get here? That’s the focus of House of Debt.
Mian and Sufi spent the
past decade compiling and analyzing microeconomic data to test
theories about
how the macroeconomy works. They conclude that inequality in
wealth and debt
combined with greater availability of credit to marginal
borrowers are a toxic
macro-economic combination. They call this the “levered
losses” view, arguing
that severe recessions occur when “asset prices collapse and
households sharply
pull back on spending,” even with “no obvious destruction of
productive capacity
occurs."
Their story starts with an accumulation of debt—lots of it. After
the Asian financial
crisis in 1997, investors were looking for safe havens to park
their money. What
they wanted were AAA-rated bonds. What they got were
mortgage-backed
securities that were rated AAA but turned out to be junk. As we
all now know—but
most of us didn’t know at the time—Wall Street firms in the
early 2000s began
slicing and dicing and then reassembling mortgage debt into
more and more exotic
and risky mortgage-backed securities in ways that made them
look risk-free.
If debt had been more equally distributed then the decline
in consumption would have been less dramatic and the
recession would have been less devastating.
But, it wasn’t just that there was more securitization. It was that
loans made to
riskier borrowers were more likely to be securitized. This both
drove the housing
bubble and made the consequences of it popping all the worse.
Mian and Sufi point
out that between 2002 and 2005, the growth in mortgage credit
and household
1/22/2018 It Wasn't Household Debt That Caused the Great
Recession - The Atlantic
https://www.theatlantic.com/business/archive/2014/05/house-of-
debt/371282/ 5/10
incomes became negatively correlated, that is, credit expanded
in areas where
incomes were declining. This makes no sense: How can you pay
back a loan if your
income is falling? They point to academic research by Yuliya
Demyanyk and Otto
Van Hemert showing the profound consequences: By 2006,
loans had become so
disconnected from prudent business practices that “an unusually
large fraction of
subprime mortgages originated in 2006 and 2007 [became]
delinquent or in
foreclosure only months later.”
As these foreclosures began to pile up, affected households cut
back sharply on
spending. Thus, the catalyst for Great Recession had begun two
years before the
dramatic demise of Lehman Brothers. In the second quarter of
2006, the collapse
in consumption started with residential investment, which fell
by a 17 percent
annual rate. Non-residential investment didn’t begin to fall until
late in 2008, but
by then households had already pared back spending sharply.
This fallout from the collapse of the housing bubble was
amplified by the unequal
distribution of net wealth. What Mian and Sufi find is that
counties with the largest
decline in total net worth—were the ones that cut back most on
spending when
house prices declined. As housing prices began falling in 2006,
in counties where
net worth had declined most, consumption fell by almost 20
percent, compared to
only five percent for the entire U.S. economy. In contrast, even
through 2008,
counties that avoided the collapse in net worth saw almost no
decline in spending.
If debt had been more equally distributed then the decline in
consumption would
have been less dramatic and the recession would have been less
devastating.
Mian and Sufi are part of a new generation of economists
who examine detailed microeconomic data to understand
the macroeconomy, giving us a deeper understanding of
how inequality affects growth and stability.
Further, they point out that you cannot have a foreclosure
crisis—or its associated
sharp fall-off in demand—without debt and the way that debt
grew during the early
2000s exacerbated the potential for a foreclosure crisis. Mian
and Sufi find that
1/22/2018 It Wasn't Household Debt That Caused the Great
Recession - The Atlantic
https://www.theatlantic.com/business/archive/2014/05/house-of-
debt/371282/ 6/10
about half of the rise in mortgage debt was among people who
lived in their homes,
not new purchasers. People took out home equity lines of credit
and used the cash
for home improvements, funds for their kids' college tuition, or
other types of
consumption. Once the crisis was in motion, about four-in-10
mortgage defaults
were among home-equity borrowers. Thus, the foreclosure crisis
was not due to
people reaching to buy homes, but to borrowing against their
primary asset. Had
they not ramped up borrowing, falling home prices would not
have affected
consumption or led to record-high foreclosures.
Finally, all this subprime mortgage debt that had been
structured into AAA-rated
mortgage-backed securities created financial instruments in
which no single
investor has the incentive or legal right to restructure the loan,
especially for loans
to low-net-worth borrowers. This led to a situation that
dramatically reduced the
capacity of homeowners to get relief in form or informal
backruptcy and increased
foreclosures. Foreclosures reduce prices more so than principal
reductions and thus
amplified the decline in home prices and the loss in wealth.
* * *
Given the troubling rise in economic inequality over the past
four decades, this
research could not be more timely. It’s not just the questions
they are asking and
the results they are finding, but also the methods they are using.
Mian and Sufi are
part of a new generation of economists who examine detailed
microeconomic data
and analysis to understand the macroeconomy, giving us a
deeper understanding
of how inequality affects economic growth and stability. They
have done this by
using detailed, microeconomic data at the county and zip-code
level to examine
debt and consumption patterns.
Mian and Sufi’s research shows that the marginal propensity to
consume—an
economics term that describes the amount of spending done
after receiving an
additional dollar—out of housing wealth depends not just on the
value of the asset
but also the debt burden, settling a near-century-old economic
debate between two
of the most prominent economists of the 20th century.
1/22/2018 It Wasn't Household Debt That Caused the Great
Recession - The Atlantic
https://www.theatlantic.com/business/archive/2014/05/house-of-
debt/371282/ 7/10
In The General Theory of Employment, Interests, and Money,
University of Cambridge
economist John Maynard Keynes argued in 1936 that the
distribution of income
mattered for the stability of the macroeconomy. Increased
spending, be it from
consumers, government, greater exports, or investment, will
multiply as it works its
way through the economy. If additional income goes into the
hands of those with a
high marginal propensity to consume then the multiplier for
consumption demand
will be relatively larger. But if additional income goes into the
hands of those with a
lower marginal propensity to consume then the multiplier on
consumption demand
will be relatively weaker.
Two decades later, University of Chicago economist Milton
Friedman
hypothesized that although rich households appear to consume
less, they have a
pretty clear sense of what their standard of living will be on
average year after year
and they adjust their savings to keep themselves at that level. In
good years, when
they get an income bonus, they will save a more while in bad
years, they won’t save
as much—or will borrow—to maintain that average standard of
living.
Yet neither Keynes nor Friedman had access to the kinds of data
now at the
fingertips of Mian and Sufi. Thus the Keynes-Friedman debate
was theoretical, not
grounded in empirical reality. Now, Mian and Sufi provide a
definite “yes” to the
question of whether we could have prevented the Great
Recession—and the
conclusion isn’t pretty. They argue that policymakers could
have seriously
mitigated the damage, pointing out that debt forgiveness would
have been much
more effective that the policies implemented because it would
have targeted
households with the largest marginal propensity to consume.
This is a failure on a
massive scale and more economists need to follow the lead of
Mian and Sufi and
look deep into the data to understand what we got wrong.
Mian and Sufi’s argument hinges on the conclusion that it was
the supply of credit
that drove the bubble and the heightened debt burdens, rather
than increased
demand from consumers. They discuss some reasons why people
may have wanted
to borrow more, such as the idea that people who expected
higher incomes were
borrowing constrained, but come down on the side that people
were just acting
1/22/2018 It Wasn't Household Debt That Caused the Great
Recession - The Atlantic
https://www.theatlantic.com/business/archive/2014/05/house-of-
debt/371282/ 8/10
irrationally—given that the massive increase in borrows during
the credit boom was
among borrowers with declining incomes, not those with rising
incomes. From this,
they conclude that “whatever the reason, however, consumers
who were offered
more money by lenders took it.”
Were people behaving irrationally? And, what (really) does that
mean? The late
1990s saw the strongest labor market in decades. The typical
male earner saw his
annual earnings finally grow, after over a decade-and-a-half of
inflation-adjusted
declines; women’s employment rates hit an all-time high of 58
percent; and the
typical family income grew by an average annual rate of just
under 2 percent. The
middle was (finally) back, so it may have been the case that
people were optimistic
that the recession of 2001 would not just be short and shallow,
but that the
recovery would look like the late 1990s.
But looking closely at the data reveals another pattern. One
thing that did not
happen during the recession of the early 2000s was a rise in
government
borrowing. The cash seeking a safe haven from the Asian
financial crisis had to go
somewhere, but the federal government wasn’t in the mood to
borrow. So those
dollars flowed willingly into the mortgage-backed securities
being peddled as AAA-
rated bonds. And the greater the demand, the more Wall Street
packaged up their
dodgy securities containing more and more subprime loans
extended to those least
able to afford credit.
The last few decades of the 2oth century also saw a number of
marked changes for
families. Women increased their labor supply steadily from the
1960s through the
high employment years of the early 1990s. By the late 1990s,
however, that long-
term rise in employment rates had stalled. The United States
went from being an
economy that had one of the largest shares of women in the
labor force to number
18 among 35 developed-economy member nations of the
Organisation for
Economic Co-operation and Development.
A variety of reasons have been presented for the sudden end in
the growth of
women’s employment beginning in the first decade of the 21st
century and
continuing today. The mainstream media play up the idea that
women are “opting
1/22/2018 It Wasn't Household Debt That Caused the Great
Recession - The Atlantic
https://www.theatlantic.com/business/archive/2014/05/house-of-
debt/371282/ 9/10
out” of careers in favor of motherhood, a story line developed
in large part by
journalists who either live in more wealthy neighborhoods and
thus see this
happening or write for publications that cater mostly to these
wealthy
neighborhoods. Yet empirical research finds that women, like
men, found it harder
to find and keep jobs due to the lackluster economic recovery
after the recession of
2001. As families sought to cope with the slow-job growth
economy in the 2000s
and a labor market that still does not provide the kinds of
supports and protections
working parents need, many turned to increasingly-readily-
available credit as a way
to cope.
Now, of course, such easy credit is no longer available. Neither
is a robust jobs
market. It may be true that it doesn’t matter why people took on
more debt prior to
the Great Recession, as Mian and Sufi contend, but today the
lessons learned then
are critically important. The story that emerged in the early
days of the Great
Recession was that too many people borrowed too much to
afford fancy houses.
That’s not what Mian and Sufi’s data show. They show that the
boom in debt
occurred among borrowers that couldn’t qualify for a
government-backed
mortgage. That the private sector sought them out in the tens of
millions to offer
loans they were demonstrably unable to repay—without worry
because these
lenders very quickly diced up those loans and sold them to
supposedly savvy
institutional investors—created the housing bubble that
exploded into the twin
crises that led to the Great Recession.
This activity produced a bubble—one that anyone could see and
one that
policymakers blithely passed off as either non-existent or
unimportant—to the
detriment of our entire economy. Subsequent reforms to our
financial system give
policymakers more tools to police housing finance, yet the
continuing over-reliance
on debt and a lack of good jobs leaves families at risk and
exposes our economy to
the whipsaw of another debt-fueled credit bubble. Mian and Sufi
deserve credit of
another kind for detailing how ensnared the American Dream is
in this tangled web
of debt finance—and how exposed the vast majority of us are to
the broader
economic consequences.
ABOUT THE AUTHOR
1/22/2018 It Wasn't Household Debt That Caused the Great
Recession - The Atlantic
https://www.theatlantic.com/business/archive/2014/05/house-of-
debt/371282/ 10/10
HEATHER BOUSHEY is the executive director and chief
economist at the Washington Center
for Equitable Growth.
https://www.theatlantic.com/author/heather-boushey/
http://equitablegrowth.org/
The topic will be Secular Stagnation. Details below:
Topic: Did the “Great Recession” Lead to Secular Stagnation
and How Should Policy Respond?
Your assignment is to write an essay that analyzes the debate
about secular stagnation in the aftermath of the Great Recession
and to recommend policies in a way that is consistent with your
diagnosis of the current situation. A complete assessment of the
secular stagnation debate requires an understanding of how the
economy got into this situation. Therefore, your essay should
discuss the sources of the Great Recession and explain why
some economists argue that the crisis led to secular stagnation.
Your analysis should cover different sides of the debate, but it
should lead to a clear statement of your own view about how the
stagnation concept does or does not apply to the current state of
U.S. economy. Based on this opinion, discuss the best path
forward for economic policy.
You need to consider the following concepts and questions:
· What was the source of the Great Recession and how did it
lead to the possibility of secular stagnation?
· Link your analysis of what has happened with the Classical
and Keynesian macroeconomic perspectives. Discuss how
aspects of these theories are (or are not) helpful in explaining
the relevant history. Also, your grade will be better if you can
build a somewhat nuanced story that demonstrates a deep
understanding of the theories.
· When discussing secular stagnation directly, I encourage you
to consider ways in which the recent recovery has been different
from what happened after earlier recessions.
· Link your policy recommendations in a consistent way to your
theoretical and empirical understanding of the secular
stagnation debate. Consider how both fiscal and monetary
policy could improve the U.S. economy over the next few years.
You should use the readings below to help guide your thinking
about the essay. You may use outside resources, but it is not
necessary to do outside research that goes beyond the readings.
The target length of the essay is 2,500 words (approximately 5
pages single spaced). Please use 12 point, Times New Roman
font.

More Related Content

Similar to Secular StagnationWhy Might Equilibriu.docx

Liquidity Risk Reporting, Measurement and Management
Liquidity Risk Reporting, Measurement and ManagementLiquidity Risk Reporting, Measurement and Management
Liquidity Risk Reporting, Measurement and Management
aseemelahi
 
Question 1Response 1Development inside and out effects t.docx
Question 1Response 1Development inside and out effects t.docxQuestion 1Response 1Development inside and out effects t.docx
Question 1Response 1Development inside and out effects t.docx
audeleypearl
 
Blackwall partners 2 qtr 2016- transient volatility part iii
Blackwall partners  2 qtr 2016- transient volatility part iiiBlackwall partners  2 qtr 2016- transient volatility part iii
Blackwall partners 2 qtr 2016- transient volatility part iii
Michael Durante
 
Monetary policy and Main Street
Monetary policy and Main StreetMonetary policy and Main Street
Monetary policy and Main Street
A.W. Berry
 
Global Macro-economics, Trends, Portfolio Implications
Global Macro-economics, Trends, Portfolio ImplicationsGlobal Macro-economics, Trends, Portfolio Implications
Global Macro-economics, Trends, Portfolio Implications
Nikunj Sanghvi
 
Covid19 Pandemic: Looming Global Recession and Impact on Bangladesh
Covid19 Pandemic: Looming Global Recession and Impact on BangladeshCovid19 Pandemic: Looming Global Recession and Impact on Bangladesh
Covid19 Pandemic: Looming Global Recession and Impact on Bangladesh
Md. Tanzirul Amin
 
Can the United States Continue to Run Current Account Deficits Ind.docx
Can the United States Continue to Run Current Account Deficits Ind.docxCan the United States Continue to Run Current Account Deficits Ind.docx
Can the United States Continue to Run Current Account Deficits Ind.docx
humphrieskalyn
 
The Fed's Asset Purchases
The Fed's Asset PurchasesThe Fed's Asset Purchases
The Fed's Asset Purchases
Jeff Green
 
World crisis of 2008 and its economic, social and geopolitical consequences
World crisis of 2008 and its economic, social and geopolitical consequencesWorld crisis of 2008 and its economic, social and geopolitical consequences
World crisis of 2008 and its economic, social and geopolitical consequences
Fernando Alcoforado
 
2009 By Niall Ferguson
2009 By Niall Ferguson2009 By Niall Ferguson
2009 By Niall Ferguson
Luis Orozco
 
2018 01-25 hm
2018 01-25 hm2018 01-25 hm
2018 01-25 hm
Mats Larsson
 
2009 Market Outlook
2009 Market Outlook2009 Market Outlook
2009 Market Outlook
Gene Balas, CFA
 
Financial Crises Final Paper
Financial Crises Final PaperFinancial Crises Final Paper
Financial Crises Final Paper
Josh Hamilton
 
MT-Fundamental Recap 2007-2009 Final
MT-Fundamental Recap  2007-2009 FinalMT-Fundamental Recap  2007-2009 Final
MT-Fundamental Recap 2007-2009 Final
Jim Welsh
 

Similar to Secular StagnationWhy Might Equilibriu.docx (14)

Liquidity Risk Reporting, Measurement and Management
Liquidity Risk Reporting, Measurement and ManagementLiquidity Risk Reporting, Measurement and Management
Liquidity Risk Reporting, Measurement and Management
 
Question 1Response 1Development inside and out effects t.docx
Question 1Response 1Development inside and out effects t.docxQuestion 1Response 1Development inside and out effects t.docx
Question 1Response 1Development inside and out effects t.docx
 
Blackwall partners 2 qtr 2016- transient volatility part iii
Blackwall partners  2 qtr 2016- transient volatility part iiiBlackwall partners  2 qtr 2016- transient volatility part iii
Blackwall partners 2 qtr 2016- transient volatility part iii
 
Monetary policy and Main Street
Monetary policy and Main StreetMonetary policy and Main Street
Monetary policy and Main Street
 
Global Macro-economics, Trends, Portfolio Implications
Global Macro-economics, Trends, Portfolio ImplicationsGlobal Macro-economics, Trends, Portfolio Implications
Global Macro-economics, Trends, Portfolio Implications
 
Covid19 Pandemic: Looming Global Recession and Impact on Bangladesh
Covid19 Pandemic: Looming Global Recession and Impact on BangladeshCovid19 Pandemic: Looming Global Recession and Impact on Bangladesh
Covid19 Pandemic: Looming Global Recession and Impact on Bangladesh
 
Can the United States Continue to Run Current Account Deficits Ind.docx
Can the United States Continue to Run Current Account Deficits Ind.docxCan the United States Continue to Run Current Account Deficits Ind.docx
Can the United States Continue to Run Current Account Deficits Ind.docx
 
The Fed's Asset Purchases
The Fed's Asset PurchasesThe Fed's Asset Purchases
The Fed's Asset Purchases
 
World crisis of 2008 and its economic, social and geopolitical consequences
World crisis of 2008 and its economic, social and geopolitical consequencesWorld crisis of 2008 and its economic, social and geopolitical consequences
World crisis of 2008 and its economic, social and geopolitical consequences
 
2009 By Niall Ferguson
2009 By Niall Ferguson2009 By Niall Ferguson
2009 By Niall Ferguson
 
2018 01-25 hm
2018 01-25 hm2018 01-25 hm
2018 01-25 hm
 
2009 Market Outlook
2009 Market Outlook2009 Market Outlook
2009 Market Outlook
 
Financial Crises Final Paper
Financial Crises Final PaperFinancial Crises Final Paper
Financial Crises Final Paper
 
MT-Fundamental Recap 2007-2009 Final
MT-Fundamental Recap  2007-2009 FinalMT-Fundamental Recap  2007-2009 Final
MT-Fundamental Recap 2007-2009 Final
 

More from jeffreye3

Select 2 particular media forum types from the following listNews.docx
Select 2 particular media forum types from the following listNews.docxSelect 2 particular media forum types from the following listNews.docx
Select 2 particular media forum types from the following listNews.docx
jeffreye3
 
Select 1 of the datasets.Set up a frequency table.docx
Select 1 of the datasets.Set up a frequency table.docxSelect 1 of the datasets.Set up a frequency table.docx
Select 1 of the datasets.Set up a frequency table.docx
jeffreye3
 
Select 1 alternative religion (e.g., Church of Scientology, Tr.docx
Select 1 alternative religion (e.g., Church of Scientology, Tr.docxSelect 1 alternative religion (e.g., Church of Scientology, Tr.docx
Select 1 alternative religion (e.g., Church of Scientology, Tr.docx
jeffreye3
 
Select 1 existing or defunct magazine or newspaper, and research its.docx
Select 1 existing or defunct magazine or newspaper, and research its.docxSelect 1 existing or defunct magazine or newspaper, and research its.docx
Select 1 existing or defunct magazine or newspaper, and research its.docx
jeffreye3
 
SeleccionarSelect the item that does not belong.¿Lógico o .docx
SeleccionarSelect the item that does not belong.¿Lógico o .docxSeleccionarSelect the item that does not belong.¿Lógico o .docx
SeleccionarSelect the item that does not belong.¿Lógico o .docx
jeffreye3
 
SeleccionarSelecciona la respuesta que mejor completa cada oración.docx
SeleccionarSelecciona la respuesta que mejor completa cada oración.docxSeleccionarSelecciona la respuesta que mejor completa cada oración.docx
SeleccionarSelecciona la respuesta que mejor completa cada oración.docx
jeffreye3
 
Segmented Assimilation Theory and theLife Model An Integrat.docx
Segmented Assimilation Theory and theLife Model An Integrat.docxSegmented Assimilation Theory and theLife Model An Integrat.docx
Segmented Assimilation Theory and theLife Model An Integrat.docx
jeffreye3
 
Seeking your ability to think about criminalsocial issues .docx
Seeking your ability to think about criminalsocial issues .docxSeeking your ability to think about criminalsocial issues .docx
Seeking your ability to think about criminalsocial issues .docx
jeffreye3
 
Seeking help with week 4 UOP PSY525 team assignment.  Only one.docx
Seeking help with week 4 UOP PSY525 team assignment.  Only one.docxSeeking help with week 4 UOP PSY525 team assignment.  Only one.docx
Seeking help with week 4 UOP PSY525 team assignment.  Only one.docx
jeffreye3
 
Seeking a minimin of one page with scholarly in-text references with.docx
Seeking a minimin of one page with scholarly in-text references with.docxSeeking a minimin of one page with scholarly in-text references with.docx
Seeking a minimin of one page with scholarly in-text references with.docx
jeffreye3
 
Seeking a 500 word document that outlines(A) who most commonly .docx
Seeking a 500 word document that outlines(A) who most commonly .docxSeeking a 500 word document that outlines(A) who most commonly .docx
Seeking a 500 word document that outlines(A) who most commonly .docx
jeffreye3
 
SEED Labs – Linux Firewall Exploration Lab 1Linux Firewall.docx
SEED Labs – Linux Firewall Exploration Lab 1Linux Firewall.docxSEED Labs – Linux Firewall Exploration Lab 1Linux Firewall.docx
SEED Labs – Linux Firewall Exploration Lab 1Linux Firewall.docx
jeffreye3
 
seek limited’s group report &meetingiiTable of C.docx
seek limited’s group report &meetingiiTable of C.docxseek limited’s group report &meetingiiTable of C.docx
seek limited’s group report &meetingiiTable of C.docx
jeffreye3
 
Seediscussions,stats,andauthorprofilesforthispublicati.docx
Seediscussions,stats,andauthorprofilesforthispublicati.docxSeediscussions,stats,andauthorprofilesforthispublicati.docx
Seediscussions,stats,andauthorprofilesforthispublicati.docx
jeffreye3
 
SEE YELLOW HIGHLIGHTED AREA BELOWPart 1.Laying the Foundat.docx
SEE YELLOW HIGHLIGHTED AREA BELOWPart 1.Laying the Foundat.docxSEE YELLOW HIGHLIGHTED AREA BELOWPart 1.Laying the Foundat.docx
SEE YELLOW HIGHLIGHTED AREA BELOWPart 1.Laying the Foundat.docx
jeffreye3
 
See ENF450 Search Strategies and the Student Resources links and sup.docx
See ENF450 Search Strategies and the Student Resources links and sup.docxSee ENF450 Search Strategies and the Student Resources links and sup.docx
See ENF450 Search Strategies and the Student Resources links and sup.docx
jeffreye3
 
Seed TagsCollect a variety of seed tags. Take photos of the .docx
Seed TagsCollect a variety of seed tags. Take photos of the .docxSeed TagsCollect a variety of seed tags. Take photos of the .docx
Seed TagsCollect a variety of seed tags. Take photos of the .docx
jeffreye3
 
see videohttpsyoutu.be-O5gsF5oylsconsider how hist.docx
see videohttpsyoutu.be-O5gsF5oylsconsider how hist.docxsee videohttpsyoutu.be-O5gsF5oylsconsider how hist.docx
see videohttpsyoutu.be-O5gsF5oylsconsider how hist.docx
jeffreye3
 
See Topic on the project 1 paperTarget- Casemanager and care.docx
See Topic on the project 1 paperTarget- Casemanager and care.docxSee Topic on the project 1 paperTarget- Casemanager and care.docx
See Topic on the project 1 paperTarget- Casemanager and care.docx
jeffreye3
 
See attachments for information.Looking for assistance on an assig.docx
See attachments for information.Looking for assistance on an assig.docxSee attachments for information.Looking for assistance on an assig.docx
See attachments for information.Looking for assistance on an assig.docx
jeffreye3
 

More from jeffreye3 (20)

Select 2 particular media forum types from the following listNews.docx
Select 2 particular media forum types from the following listNews.docxSelect 2 particular media forum types from the following listNews.docx
Select 2 particular media forum types from the following listNews.docx
 
Select 1 of the datasets.Set up a frequency table.docx
Select 1 of the datasets.Set up a frequency table.docxSelect 1 of the datasets.Set up a frequency table.docx
Select 1 of the datasets.Set up a frequency table.docx
 
Select 1 alternative religion (e.g., Church of Scientology, Tr.docx
Select 1 alternative religion (e.g., Church of Scientology, Tr.docxSelect 1 alternative religion (e.g., Church of Scientology, Tr.docx
Select 1 alternative religion (e.g., Church of Scientology, Tr.docx
 
Select 1 existing or defunct magazine or newspaper, and research its.docx
Select 1 existing or defunct magazine or newspaper, and research its.docxSelect 1 existing or defunct magazine or newspaper, and research its.docx
Select 1 existing or defunct magazine or newspaper, and research its.docx
 
SeleccionarSelect the item that does not belong.¿Lógico o .docx
SeleccionarSelect the item that does not belong.¿Lógico o .docxSeleccionarSelect the item that does not belong.¿Lógico o .docx
SeleccionarSelect the item that does not belong.¿Lógico o .docx
 
SeleccionarSelecciona la respuesta que mejor completa cada oración.docx
SeleccionarSelecciona la respuesta que mejor completa cada oración.docxSeleccionarSelecciona la respuesta que mejor completa cada oración.docx
SeleccionarSelecciona la respuesta que mejor completa cada oración.docx
 
Segmented Assimilation Theory and theLife Model An Integrat.docx
Segmented Assimilation Theory and theLife Model An Integrat.docxSegmented Assimilation Theory and theLife Model An Integrat.docx
Segmented Assimilation Theory and theLife Model An Integrat.docx
 
Seeking your ability to think about criminalsocial issues .docx
Seeking your ability to think about criminalsocial issues .docxSeeking your ability to think about criminalsocial issues .docx
Seeking your ability to think about criminalsocial issues .docx
 
Seeking help with week 4 UOP PSY525 team assignment.  Only one.docx
Seeking help with week 4 UOP PSY525 team assignment.  Only one.docxSeeking help with week 4 UOP PSY525 team assignment.  Only one.docx
Seeking help with week 4 UOP PSY525 team assignment.  Only one.docx
 
Seeking a minimin of one page with scholarly in-text references with.docx
Seeking a minimin of one page with scholarly in-text references with.docxSeeking a minimin of one page with scholarly in-text references with.docx
Seeking a minimin of one page with scholarly in-text references with.docx
 
Seeking a 500 word document that outlines(A) who most commonly .docx
Seeking a 500 word document that outlines(A) who most commonly .docxSeeking a 500 word document that outlines(A) who most commonly .docx
Seeking a 500 word document that outlines(A) who most commonly .docx
 
SEED Labs – Linux Firewall Exploration Lab 1Linux Firewall.docx
SEED Labs – Linux Firewall Exploration Lab 1Linux Firewall.docxSEED Labs – Linux Firewall Exploration Lab 1Linux Firewall.docx
SEED Labs – Linux Firewall Exploration Lab 1Linux Firewall.docx
 
seek limited’s group report &meetingiiTable of C.docx
seek limited’s group report &meetingiiTable of C.docxseek limited’s group report &meetingiiTable of C.docx
seek limited’s group report &meetingiiTable of C.docx
 
Seediscussions,stats,andauthorprofilesforthispublicati.docx
Seediscussions,stats,andauthorprofilesforthispublicati.docxSeediscussions,stats,andauthorprofilesforthispublicati.docx
Seediscussions,stats,andauthorprofilesforthispublicati.docx
 
SEE YELLOW HIGHLIGHTED AREA BELOWPart 1.Laying the Foundat.docx
SEE YELLOW HIGHLIGHTED AREA BELOWPart 1.Laying the Foundat.docxSEE YELLOW HIGHLIGHTED AREA BELOWPart 1.Laying the Foundat.docx
SEE YELLOW HIGHLIGHTED AREA BELOWPart 1.Laying the Foundat.docx
 
See ENF450 Search Strategies and the Student Resources links and sup.docx
See ENF450 Search Strategies and the Student Resources links and sup.docxSee ENF450 Search Strategies and the Student Resources links and sup.docx
See ENF450 Search Strategies and the Student Resources links and sup.docx
 
Seed TagsCollect a variety of seed tags. Take photos of the .docx
Seed TagsCollect a variety of seed tags. Take photos of the .docxSeed TagsCollect a variety of seed tags. Take photos of the .docx
Seed TagsCollect a variety of seed tags. Take photos of the .docx
 
see videohttpsyoutu.be-O5gsF5oylsconsider how hist.docx
see videohttpsyoutu.be-O5gsF5oylsconsider how hist.docxsee videohttpsyoutu.be-O5gsF5oylsconsider how hist.docx
see videohttpsyoutu.be-O5gsF5oylsconsider how hist.docx
 
See Topic on the project 1 paperTarget- Casemanager and care.docx
See Topic on the project 1 paperTarget- Casemanager and care.docxSee Topic on the project 1 paperTarget- Casemanager and care.docx
See Topic on the project 1 paperTarget- Casemanager and care.docx
 
See attachments for information.Looking for assistance on an assig.docx
See attachments for information.Looking for assistance on an assig.docxSee attachments for information.Looking for assistance on an assig.docx
See attachments for information.Looking for assistance on an assig.docx
 

Recently uploaded

Assessment and Planning in Educational technology.pptx
Assessment and Planning in Educational technology.pptxAssessment and Planning in Educational technology.pptx
Assessment and Planning in Educational technology.pptx
Kavitha Krishnan
 
BÀI TẬP BỔ TRỢ TIẾNG ANH 8 CẢ NĂM - GLOBAL SUCCESS - NĂM HỌC 2023-2024 (CÓ FI...
BÀI TẬP BỔ TRỢ TIẾNG ANH 8 CẢ NĂM - GLOBAL SUCCESS - NĂM HỌC 2023-2024 (CÓ FI...BÀI TẬP BỔ TRỢ TIẾNG ANH 8 CẢ NĂM - GLOBAL SUCCESS - NĂM HỌC 2023-2024 (CÓ FI...
BÀI TẬP BỔ TRỢ TIẾNG ANH 8 CẢ NĂM - GLOBAL SUCCESS - NĂM HỌC 2023-2024 (CÓ FI...
Nguyen Thanh Tu Collection
 
Top five deadliest dog breeds in America
Top five deadliest dog breeds in AmericaTop five deadliest dog breeds in America
Top five deadliest dog breeds in America
Bisnar Chase Personal Injury Attorneys
 
Pollock and Snow "DEIA in the Scholarly Landscape, Session One: Setting Expec...
Pollock and Snow "DEIA in the Scholarly Landscape, Session One: Setting Expec...Pollock and Snow "DEIA in the Scholarly Landscape, Session One: Setting Expec...
Pollock and Snow "DEIA in the Scholarly Landscape, Session One: Setting Expec...
National Information Standards Organization (NISO)
 
How to Add Chatter in the odoo 17 ERP Module
How to Add Chatter in the odoo 17 ERP ModuleHow to Add Chatter in the odoo 17 ERP Module
How to Add Chatter in the odoo 17 ERP Module
Celine George
 
Hindi varnamala | hindi alphabet PPT.pdf
Hindi varnamala | hindi alphabet PPT.pdfHindi varnamala | hindi alphabet PPT.pdf
Hindi varnamala | hindi alphabet PPT.pdf
Dr. Mulla Adam Ali
 
RPMS TEMPLATE FOR SCHOOL YEAR 2023-2024 FOR TEACHER 1 TO TEACHER 3
RPMS TEMPLATE FOR SCHOOL YEAR 2023-2024 FOR TEACHER 1 TO TEACHER 3RPMS TEMPLATE FOR SCHOOL YEAR 2023-2024 FOR TEACHER 1 TO TEACHER 3
RPMS TEMPLATE FOR SCHOOL YEAR 2023-2024 FOR TEACHER 1 TO TEACHER 3
IreneSebastianRueco1
 
Film vocab for eal 3 students: Australia the movie
Film vocab for eal 3 students: Australia the movieFilm vocab for eal 3 students: Australia the movie
Film vocab for eal 3 students: Australia the movie
Nicholas Montgomery
 
Digital Artifact 1 - 10VCD Environments Unit
Digital Artifact 1 - 10VCD Environments UnitDigital Artifact 1 - 10VCD Environments Unit
Digital Artifact 1 - 10VCD Environments Unit
chanes7
 
Azure Interview Questions and Answers PDF By ScholarHat
Azure Interview Questions and Answers PDF By ScholarHatAzure Interview Questions and Answers PDF By ScholarHat
Azure Interview Questions and Answers PDF By ScholarHat
Scholarhat
 
Life upper-Intermediate B2 Workbook for student
Life upper-Intermediate B2 Workbook for studentLife upper-Intermediate B2 Workbook for student
Life upper-Intermediate B2 Workbook for student
NgcHiNguyn25
 
World environment day ppt For 5 June 2024
World environment day ppt For 5 June 2024World environment day ppt For 5 June 2024
World environment day ppt For 5 June 2024
ak6969907
 
How to Fix the Import Error in the Odoo 17
How to Fix the Import Error in the Odoo 17How to Fix the Import Error in the Odoo 17
How to Fix the Import Error in the Odoo 17
Celine George
 
ANATOMY AND BIOMECHANICS OF HIP JOINT.pdf
ANATOMY AND BIOMECHANICS OF HIP JOINT.pdfANATOMY AND BIOMECHANICS OF HIP JOINT.pdf
ANATOMY AND BIOMECHANICS OF HIP JOINT.pdf
Priyankaranawat4
 
Exploiting Artificial Intelligence for Empowering Researchers and Faculty, In...
Exploiting Artificial Intelligence for Empowering Researchers and Faculty, In...Exploiting Artificial Intelligence for Empowering Researchers and Faculty, In...
Exploiting Artificial Intelligence for Empowering Researchers and Faculty, In...
Dr. Vinod Kumar Kanvaria
 
Smart-Money for SMC traders good time and ICT
Smart-Money for SMC traders good time and ICTSmart-Money for SMC traders good time and ICT
Smart-Money for SMC traders good time and ICT
simonomuemu
 
The Diamonds of 2023-2024 in the IGRA collection
The Diamonds of 2023-2024 in the IGRA collectionThe Diamonds of 2023-2024 in the IGRA collection
The Diamonds of 2023-2024 in the IGRA collection
Israel Genealogy Research Association
 
The basics of sentences session 5pptx.pptx
The basics of sentences session 5pptx.pptxThe basics of sentences session 5pptx.pptx
The basics of sentences session 5pptx.pptx
heathfieldcps1
 
Natural birth techniques - Mrs.Akanksha Trivedi Rama University
Natural birth techniques - Mrs.Akanksha Trivedi Rama UniversityNatural birth techniques - Mrs.Akanksha Trivedi Rama University
Natural birth techniques - Mrs.Akanksha Trivedi Rama University
Akanksha trivedi rama nursing college kanpur.
 
Advanced Java[Extra Concepts, Not Difficult].docx
Advanced Java[Extra Concepts, Not Difficult].docxAdvanced Java[Extra Concepts, Not Difficult].docx
Advanced Java[Extra Concepts, Not Difficult].docx
adhitya5119
 

Recently uploaded (20)

Assessment and Planning in Educational technology.pptx
Assessment and Planning in Educational technology.pptxAssessment and Planning in Educational technology.pptx
Assessment and Planning in Educational technology.pptx
 
BÀI TẬP BỔ TRỢ TIẾNG ANH 8 CẢ NĂM - GLOBAL SUCCESS - NĂM HỌC 2023-2024 (CÓ FI...
BÀI TẬP BỔ TRỢ TIẾNG ANH 8 CẢ NĂM - GLOBAL SUCCESS - NĂM HỌC 2023-2024 (CÓ FI...BÀI TẬP BỔ TRỢ TIẾNG ANH 8 CẢ NĂM - GLOBAL SUCCESS - NĂM HỌC 2023-2024 (CÓ FI...
BÀI TẬP BỔ TRỢ TIẾNG ANH 8 CẢ NĂM - GLOBAL SUCCESS - NĂM HỌC 2023-2024 (CÓ FI...
 
Top five deadliest dog breeds in America
Top five deadliest dog breeds in AmericaTop five deadliest dog breeds in America
Top five deadliest dog breeds in America
 
Pollock and Snow "DEIA in the Scholarly Landscape, Session One: Setting Expec...
Pollock and Snow "DEIA in the Scholarly Landscape, Session One: Setting Expec...Pollock and Snow "DEIA in the Scholarly Landscape, Session One: Setting Expec...
Pollock and Snow "DEIA in the Scholarly Landscape, Session One: Setting Expec...
 
How to Add Chatter in the odoo 17 ERP Module
How to Add Chatter in the odoo 17 ERP ModuleHow to Add Chatter in the odoo 17 ERP Module
How to Add Chatter in the odoo 17 ERP Module
 
Hindi varnamala | hindi alphabet PPT.pdf
Hindi varnamala | hindi alphabet PPT.pdfHindi varnamala | hindi alphabet PPT.pdf
Hindi varnamala | hindi alphabet PPT.pdf
 
RPMS TEMPLATE FOR SCHOOL YEAR 2023-2024 FOR TEACHER 1 TO TEACHER 3
RPMS TEMPLATE FOR SCHOOL YEAR 2023-2024 FOR TEACHER 1 TO TEACHER 3RPMS TEMPLATE FOR SCHOOL YEAR 2023-2024 FOR TEACHER 1 TO TEACHER 3
RPMS TEMPLATE FOR SCHOOL YEAR 2023-2024 FOR TEACHER 1 TO TEACHER 3
 
Film vocab for eal 3 students: Australia the movie
Film vocab for eal 3 students: Australia the movieFilm vocab for eal 3 students: Australia the movie
Film vocab for eal 3 students: Australia the movie
 
Digital Artifact 1 - 10VCD Environments Unit
Digital Artifact 1 - 10VCD Environments UnitDigital Artifact 1 - 10VCD Environments Unit
Digital Artifact 1 - 10VCD Environments Unit
 
Azure Interview Questions and Answers PDF By ScholarHat
Azure Interview Questions and Answers PDF By ScholarHatAzure Interview Questions and Answers PDF By ScholarHat
Azure Interview Questions and Answers PDF By ScholarHat
 
Life upper-Intermediate B2 Workbook for student
Life upper-Intermediate B2 Workbook for studentLife upper-Intermediate B2 Workbook for student
Life upper-Intermediate B2 Workbook for student
 
World environment day ppt For 5 June 2024
World environment day ppt For 5 June 2024World environment day ppt For 5 June 2024
World environment day ppt For 5 June 2024
 
How to Fix the Import Error in the Odoo 17
How to Fix the Import Error in the Odoo 17How to Fix the Import Error in the Odoo 17
How to Fix the Import Error in the Odoo 17
 
ANATOMY AND BIOMECHANICS OF HIP JOINT.pdf
ANATOMY AND BIOMECHANICS OF HIP JOINT.pdfANATOMY AND BIOMECHANICS OF HIP JOINT.pdf
ANATOMY AND BIOMECHANICS OF HIP JOINT.pdf
 
Exploiting Artificial Intelligence for Empowering Researchers and Faculty, In...
Exploiting Artificial Intelligence for Empowering Researchers and Faculty, In...Exploiting Artificial Intelligence for Empowering Researchers and Faculty, In...
Exploiting Artificial Intelligence for Empowering Researchers and Faculty, In...
 
Smart-Money for SMC traders good time and ICT
Smart-Money for SMC traders good time and ICTSmart-Money for SMC traders good time and ICT
Smart-Money for SMC traders good time and ICT
 
The Diamonds of 2023-2024 in the IGRA collection
The Diamonds of 2023-2024 in the IGRA collectionThe Diamonds of 2023-2024 in the IGRA collection
The Diamonds of 2023-2024 in the IGRA collection
 
The basics of sentences session 5pptx.pptx
The basics of sentences session 5pptx.pptxThe basics of sentences session 5pptx.pptx
The basics of sentences session 5pptx.pptx
 
Natural birth techniques - Mrs.Akanksha Trivedi Rama University
Natural birth techniques - Mrs.Akanksha Trivedi Rama UniversityNatural birth techniques - Mrs.Akanksha Trivedi Rama University
Natural birth techniques - Mrs.Akanksha Trivedi Rama University
 
Advanced Java[Extra Concepts, Not Difficult].docx
Advanced Java[Extra Concepts, Not Difficult].docxAdvanced Java[Extra Concepts, Not Difficult].docx
Advanced Java[Extra Concepts, Not Difficult].docx
 

Secular StagnationWhy Might Equilibriu.docx

  • 1. Secular Stagnation Why Might Equilibrium Real Rates Have Fallen? Increased Savings Changes in distribution of income and profits share Reserve accumulation or capital flight Increasing deleveraging and retirement preparation Decreases in Investment Propensity Declining growth rate of population and/or technology Demassification of the economy Fall in price of capital goods Other factors Increased global save asset demand
  • 2. 3/14/2020 The Age of Secular Stagnation | Larry Summers larrysummers.com/2016/02/17/the-age-of-secular-stagnation/ 1/6 HOME CONTACT SEARCH Lawrence H. Summers is the Charles W. Eliot University Professor and President Emeritus at Harvard University. He served as the 71st Secretary of the Treasury for President Clinton and the Director of the National Economic Council for President Obama. FULL BIO Larry Summers on SECULAR STAGNATION READ MORE FOLLOW @LHSUMMERS on Twitter Larry Summers COMMENTARY RESEARCH TEACHING MEDIA RESOURCES Summers published an article title, “The Age of Secular Stagnation: What It Is and What to Do About It,” in the
  • 3. February issue of Foreign A�airs. The article explores how expansionary �scal policy by the U.S. government can help overcome secular stagnation problems and get growth back on track. The Age of Secular Stagnation: What It Is and What to Do About It February 15, 2016 published in Foreign A�airs As surprising as the recent �nancial crisis [1] and recession were, the behavior of the world’s industrialized economies and �nancial markets during the recovery [2] has been even more so. Most observers expected the unusually deep recession to be followed by an unusually rapid recovery, with output and employment returning to trend levels relatively quickly. Yet even with the U.S. Federal Reserve [3]’s aggressive monetary policies, the recovery (both in the United States and around the globe) has fallen signi�cantly short of predictions and has been far weaker than its predecessors [4]. Had the American economy performed as the Congressional Budget O�ce fore cast in August 2009—after the stimulus had been passed and the recovery had started—U.S. GDP today would be about $1.3 trillion higher than it is. Almost no one in 2009 imagined that U.S. interest rates would stay near zero for six
  • 4. years, that key interest rates in Europe would turn negative, and that central banks in the G-7 would collectively expand their balance sheets by more than $5 trillion. Had economists been told such monetary policies lay ahead, moreover, they would have con�dently predicted that in�ation would become a serious problem—and would have been shocked to �nd out that across the United States, Europe, and Japan, it has generally remained well below two percent. In the wake of the crisis, governments’ debt-to-GDP ratios have risen sharply, from 41 percent in 2008 to 74 percent today in the United States, from 47 percent to 70 percent in Europe, and from 95 percent to 126 percent in Japan. Yet long-term interest rates are still remarkably low, with ten-year government bond rates at around two percent in the United States, around 0.5 percent in Germany, and around 0.2 percent in Japan as of the beginning of 2016. Such low long-term rates suggest that markets currently expect both low in�ation and low real interest rates to continue for many years. With appropriate caveats about the complexities of drawing inferences from indexed bond markets, it is fair to say that in�ation for the entire industrial world is expected to be close to one percent for another decade and that real interest rates are expected to be around zero over that time frame. In other words, nearly seven years into the U.S. recovery, markets are not expecting “normal” conditions to return anytime soon.
  • 5. The key to understanding this situation lies in the concept of secular stagnation [5], �rst put forward by the economist Alvin Hansen in the 1930s. The economies of the industrial world, in this view, su�er from an imbalance resulting from an increasing propensity to save and a decreasing propensity to invest. The result is that excessive saving acts as a drag on demand, reducing growth and in�ation, and the imbalance between savings and investment pulls down real interest rates. When signi�cant growth is achieved, meanwhile—as in the United States between 2003 and 2007—it comes from dangerous levels of borrowing that translate excess savings into unsustainable levels of investment (which in this case emerged as a housing bubble). Other explanations for what is happening have been proposed, notably Kenneth Rogo�’s theory of a debt overhang, Robert Gordon [6]’s theory of supply-side headwinds, Ben Bernanke’s theory of a savings glut [7], and Paul Krugman’s theory of a liquidity trap. All of these have some validity, but the secular stagnation theory o�ers the most The Age of Secular Stagnation Print Email 258 36
  • 6. http://larrysummers.com/ http://larrysummers.com/contact/ http://larrysummers.com/biography/ http://larrysummers.com/category/secular-stagnation/ http://larrysummers.com/category/secular-stagnation/ https://twitter.com/LHSummers http://larrysummers.com/ http://larrysummers.com/commentary/ http://larrysummers.com/research/ http://larrysummers.com/teaching/ http://larrysummers.com/press-contacts/ https://www.foreignaffairs.com/reviews/2015-02-16/can- economists-learn https://www.foreignaffairs.com/reviews/review-essay/second- great-depression https://www.foreignaffairs.com/articles/united-states/2012-04- 23/all-presidents-central-bankers https://www.foreignaffairs.com/articles/united-states/2011-06- 29/america-s-weak-recovery http://www.economist.com/blogs/graphicdetail/2014/11/secular- stagnation-graphics https://www.foreignaffairs.com/reviews/review-essay/2016-01- 28/innovation-over http://www.brookings.edu/blogs/ben- bernanke/posts/2015/04/01-why-interest-rates-low-global- savings-glut http://larrysummers.com/2016/02/17/the-age-of-secular- stagnation/?share=email&nb=1 3/14/2020 The Age of Secular Stagnation | Larry Summers larrysummers.com/2016/02/17/the-age-of-secular-stagnation/ 2/6
  • 7. comprehensive account of the situation and the best basis for policy prescriptions. The good news is that although developments in China [8] and elsewhere raise the risks that global economic conditions will deteriorate, an expansionary �scal policy by the U.S. government can help overcome the secular stagnation problem and get growth back on track. STUCK IN NEUTRAL Just as the price of wheat adjusts to balance the supply of and demand for wheat, it is natural to suppose that interest rates—the price of money— adjust to balance the supply of savings and the demand for investment in an economy. Excess savings tend to drive interest rates down, and excess investment demand tends to drive them up. Following the Swedish economist Knut Wicksell, it is common to refer to the real interest rate that balances saving and investment at full employment as the “natural,” or “neutral,” real interest rate. Secular stagnation occurs when neutral real interest rates are su�ciently low that they cannot be achieved through conventional central- bank policies. At that point, desired levels of saving exceed desired levels of investment, leading to shortfalls in demand and stunted growth. This picture �ts with much of what we have seen in recent years. Real interest rates are very low, demand has been sluggish, and in�ation is low, just as one would expect in the
  • 8. presence of excess saving. Absent many good new investment opportunities, savings have tended to �ow into existing assets, causing asset price in�ation. For secular stagnation to be a plausible hypothesis, there have to be good reasons to suppose that neutral real interest rates have been declining and are now abnormally low. And in fact, a number of recent studies have tried to look at this question and have generally found declines of several percentage points. Even more convincing is the increasing body of evidence suggesting that over the last generation, various factors have increased the propensity of populations in developed countries to save and reduced their propensity to invest. Greater saving has been driven by increases in inequality and in the share of income going to the wealthy, increases in uncertainty about the length of retirement and the availability of bene�ts, reductions in the ability to borrow (especially against housing), and a greater accumulation of assets by foreign central banks and sovereign wealth funds. Reduced investment has been driven by slower growth in the labor force, the availability of cheaper capital goods, and tighter credit (with lending more highly regulated than before). Perhaps most important, the new economy [9] tends to conserve capital. Apple and Google, for example, are the two largest U.S. companies and are eager to push the frontiers of technology [10] forward, yet both are awash in cash
  • 9. and are under pressure to distribute more of it to their shareholders. Think about Airbnb’s impact on hotel construction, Uber’s impact on automobile demand, Amazon’s impact on the construction of malls, or the more general impact of information technology on the demand for copiers, printers, and o�ce space. And in a period of rapid technological change, it can make sense to defer investment lest new technology soon make the old obsolete. Various studies have explored the impact of these factors and attempted to estimate the extent to which they have reduced neutral real interest rates. The most recent and thorough of these, by Lukasz Rachel and Thomas Smith at the Bank of England, concluded that for the industrial world, neutral real interest rates have declined by about 4.5 percentage points over the last 30 years and are likely to stay low in the future. Together with the current price of long-term bonds, this suggests that the kind of Japan- style stagnation that has plagued the industrial world in recent years may be with us for quite some time. DIFFERENTIAL DIAGNOSIS Not all economists are sold on the secular stagnation hypothesis. Building on the monumental history of �nancial crises he wrote with Carmen Reinhart, for example, Rogo� ascribes current di�culties to excessive debt buildups
  • 10. and subsequent deleveraging. But although these surely contributed to the �nancial crisis, they seem insu�cient to account for the prolonged slow recovery. Moreover, the debt buildups theory provides no natural explanation for the generation-long trend toward lower neutral real interest rates. It seems more logical to see the debt buildups decried by Rogo� as not simply exogenous events but rather the consequence of a growing excess of saving over investment and the easy monetary policies necessary to maintain full employment. https://www.foreignaffairs.com/articles/china/2016-01-11/end- chinas-rise https://www.foreignaffairs.com/articles/2015-12-12/fourth- industrial-revolution https://www.foreignaffairs.com/reviews/review-essay/thinkers- and-tinkerers 3/14/2020 The Age of Secular Stagnation | Larry Summers larrysummers.com/2016/02/17/the-age-of-secular-stagnation/ 3/6 Gordon, meanwhile, has argued for what might be called supply-side secular stagnation —a fundamental decline in the rate of productivity growth relative to its golden age, from 1870 to 1970. Gordon is likely right that over the next several years, the growth in the potential output of the American economy and in the real wages of American
  • 11. workers will be quite slow. But if the primary culprit were declining supply (as opposed to declining demand), one would expect to see in�ation accelerate rather than decelerate. For a decade, Bernanke has emphasized the idea of a savings glut emanating from cash thrown o� by emerging markets. This was indeed an important factor in adding to excess saving in the developed world a decade ago, and it may well be again if emerging markets continue to experience growing capital �ight. But both the timing and the scale of capital export from emerging markets make it unlikely that it is the principal reason for the major recent declines in neutral real interest rates. Krugman and some others have sought to explain recent events and make policy recommendations based on the old Keynesian concept of a liquidity trap [11]. As Krugman has emphasized, this line of thinking is parallel to the secular stagnation one. But most treatments of the liquidity trap treat it as a temporary phenomenon rather than a potentially permanent state of a�airs, which is what the evidence seems to be showing. Perhaps the most comforting alternative view is that secular stagnation may have indeed occurred in the past but is no longer operating in the present. With the unemployment rate down to �ve percent and the Fed embarked on a tightening cycle, the argument
  • 12. runs, indicators will start returning to earlier, higher growth trends. Perhaps. But markets are betting that the Fed will not be able to tighten monetary policy nearly as much as it expects, and if another recession starts in the next few years, cuts will soon bring interest rates back down to the zero lower bound. LET’S GET FISCAL Up to the 1970s, most economists believed that if governments managed demand properly, their countries’ economies could enjoy low unemployment and high output with relatively modest in�ation. The proper task of macroeconomists, it followed, was to use monetary and �scal policy to manage demand well. But this thinking was eventually challenged from two directions—in theory, by Milton Friedman [12], Robert Lucas, and others, and in practice, by the experience of high in�ation together with high unemployment. The emergence of such “stag�ation” in the late 1970s [13] led to general acceptance of the natural-rate hypothesis, the idea that abnormally low unemployment causes in�ation to accelerate. According to this view, since policymakers would not accept permanently rising rates of in�ation, economies would tend to �uctuate around a natural rate of unemployment, determined by factors such as labor �exibility, the availability of bene�ts, and the e�ectiveness of hiring and job searches. By skillfully
  • 13. managing demand, policymakers could aspire to reduce the amplitude of the �uctuations—and although they could determine the average rate of in�ation, they could not raise the average level of output. By the mid 1980s, once in�ation had been brought down from double-digit levels, a consensus on macroeconomic policy emerged. The central objective of policy, most mainstream economists believed, should be to achieve a low and relatively stable rate of in�ation, since there were no permanent gains to be had from higher in�ation. This could best be accomplished, it was thought, by �rmly establishing the political independence of central banks and by setting in�ation targets in order to control expectations. Fiscal policy, meanwhile, was not considered to have a primary role in managing demand, because it was slow acting and might push interest rates up and because monetary policy could do what was needed. Seen through the lens of the secular stagnation hypothesis, however, all these propositions are problematic. If it were possible to avoid secular stagnation, then it would indeed be possible to increase average levels of output substantially, raising the stakes for demand management policy. The danger in monetary policy, moreover, lies not in politicians eager to in�ate away problems but in bankers refusing to generate enough demand to bring in�ation up to target levels and permit reductions in real
  • 14. interest rates. And �scal policy, �nally, takes on new signi�cance as a tool in economic stabilization. http://krugman.blogs.nytimes.com/2013/04/11/monetary-policy- in-a-liquidity-trap/?_r=0 https://www.foreignaffairs.com/reviews/capsule-review/2007- 05-01/milton-friedman-biography https://www.foreignaffairs.com/articles/united-states/1979-09- 01/stagflation-how-we-got-it-how-get-out 3/14/2020 The Age of Secular Stagnation | Larry Summers larrysummers.com/2016/02/17/the-age-of-secular-stagnation/ 4/6 As of yet, none of these principles has been fully accepted by policymakers in the advanced industrial world. It is true that central banks have sought, through quantitative easing, to loosen monetary conditions even with short-term interest rates at rock bottom. But they have treated these policies as a short-term expedient, not a longer- term necessity. More important, these policies are running into diminishing returns and giving rise to increasingly toxic side e�ects. Sustained low rates tend to promote excess leverage, risk taking, and asset bubbles. This does not mean that quantitative easing was mistaken. Without such policies, output would likely be even lower, and the world economy might well have tipped into de�ation. But monetary-policy makers need to acknowledge much more
  • 15. explicitly that neutral real rates have fallen substantially and that the task now is to adjust policy accordingly. This could include setting targets for nominal GDP growth rather than in�ation, investing in a wider range of risk assets, making plans to allow base rates to turn negative, and underscoring the importance of avoiding a new recession. When the primary policy challenge for central banks was establishing credibility that the printing press was under control, it was appropriate for them to jealously guard their independence. When the challenge is to accelerate, rather than brake, economies, more cooperation with domestic �scal authorities and foreign counterparts is necessary. The core problem of secular stagnation is that the neutral real interest rate is too low. This rate, however, cannot be increased through monetary policy. Indeed, to the extent that easy money works by accelerating investments and pulling forward demand, it will actually reduce neutral real rates later on. That is why primary responsibility for addressing secular stagnation should rest with �scal policy. An expansionary �scal policy can reduce national savings, raise neutral real interest rates, and stimulate growth. Fiscal policy has other virtues as well, particularly when pursued through public investment. A time of low real interest rates, low materials prices, and high construction unemployment is the ideal moment for a large public investment
  • 16. program. It is tragic, therefore, that in the United States today, federal infrastructure investment, net of depreciation, is running close to zero, and net government investment is lower than at any time in nearly six decades. It is true that an expansionary �scal policy would increase de�cits, and many worry that running larger de�cits would place larger burdens on later generations, who will already face the challenges of an aging society. But those future generations will be better o� owing lots of money in long-term bonds at low rates in a currency they can print than they would be inheriting a vast deferred maintenance liability. Traditional concern with �scal de�cits has focused on their impact in pushing up interest rates and retarding investment. Yet by setting yields so low and bond prices so high, markets are sending a clear signal that they want more, not less, government debt. By stimulating growth and enabling an in�ation increase that would permit a reduction in real capital costs, �scal expansion now would crowd investment in rather than out. Well- intentioned proposals to curtail prospective pension bene�ts, in contrast, might make matters even worse by encouraging increased saving and reduced consumption, thus exacerbating secular stagnation. The main constraint on the industrial world’s economy today is on the demand, rather than the supply, side. This means that measures that increase
  • 17. potential supply by promoting �exibility are therefore less important than measures that o�er the potential to increase demand, such as regulatory reform and business tax reform. Other structural policies that would promote demand include steps to accelerate investments in renewable technologies that could replace fossil fuels and measures to raise the share of total income going to those with a high propensity to consume, such as support for unions and increased minimum wages. Thus, John Maynard Keynes, writing in a similar situation during the late 1930s, rightly emphasized the need for policy approaches that both promoted business con�dence—the cheapest form of stimulus—and increased labor compensation. TO HANGZHOU AND BEYOND If each of the countries facing secular stagnation today were to confront it successfully on its own, the results would be very favorable for the global economy. But international focus and coordination have crucial additional roles to play. Secular stagnation, after all, increases the contagion from economic weakness. In normal times, if the rest of the world economy su�ers, the United States or any other a�ected 3/14/2020 The Age of Secular Stagnation | Larry Summers
  • 18. larrysummers.com/2016/02/17/the-age-of-secular-stagnation/ 5/6 economy can o�set the loss of demand and competitiveness through monetary easing. With monetary policy already at its lower limit, however, additional easing is impossible (or at least much more di�cult), and so each country’s stake in the strength of the global economy is greatly magni�ed. Secular stagnation also increases the danger of competitive monetary easing and even of currency wars. Looser money, starting with near-zero capital costs, is likely to generate demand primarily through increases in competitiveness. This is a zero-sum game, since currency movements switch demand from one country to another rather than increase it globally. Fiscal expansions, in contrast, raise demand on a global basis. International coordination is thus necessary to avoid an excessive and self-defeating reliance on monetary policy and achieve a mutually rewarding reliance on �scal policy to address problems. Movements in commodity prices in recent months have shown that events in emerging markets, especially China, can have signi�cant impacts globally. It now appears likely that more capital will �ow out of emerging markets and less will �ow in than has been the case in recent years. These capital out�ows and the consequent increases in net exports will further reduce demand and neutral real rates in the
  • 19. developed world, thereby exacerbating secular stagnation. Policies that help restore con�dence in emerging markets, therefore, will also strengthen the global economy. These issues were recognized at the successful G-20 summit in London in April 2009 (although the problems were misdiagnosed as cyclical and temporary rather than secular and enduring). The common commitments undertaken there to engage in �scal expansion, strengthen �nancial regulation, resist trade protection, and enhance the capacity of international �nancial institutions to respond to problems in emerging markets were e�ective in halting the collapse of the global economy. Unfortunately, subsequent G-20 summits returned to their traditional lethargy and misguided preoccupation with �scal austerity, monetary normalization, and moral hazard, ending up missing opportunities to accelerate the recovery. This year, the Chinese will host a G-20 summit in September. If China chooses to recognize how important global growth is for its economy, and how important its economy is for global growth, it could perform a great service by reinvigorating international economic cooperation. The key priority in Hangzhou—as it was in London back in 2009—should be increasing global demand and making sure that it picks up particularly in those countries where there is the most economic slack.
  • 20. In this regard, China’s decisions about its own economic a�airs will be crucial. To date, the international community has joined Chinese �nancial o�cials in urging China’s political leadership to pursue �nancial liberalization. This is surely correct for the long run. But it may well be in China’s and the global interest that the liberalization process proceed more gradually than is currently envisioned, so that capital out�ows from China do not threaten China’s own �nancial stability and spread weakness to the global economy at large. As the euro has declined sharply, meanwhile, any recovery that Europe has achieved has come largely from increases in competitiveness that reduce growth elsewhere. Germany now leads the world with a trade surplus equal to a whopping eight percent of GDP. The global community should encourage Europe to generate domestic demand as it seeks to expand its economy. One more priority in Hangzhou should be promoting global infrastructure investment. In this regard, the Chinese-led Asian Infrastructure Investment Bank [14] is a valuable step forward, and it should be strongly supported by the global community, even as it is encouraged to respect international norms and standards relating to issues such as environmental protection and integrity in procurement. And e�orts to support infrastructure investment elsewhere, such as the Obama administration’s Power Africa
  • 21. initiative, should be carried forward. Secular stagnation and the slow growth and �nancial instability associated with it have political as well as economic consequences. If middle-class living standards were increasing at traditional rates, politics across the developed world would likely be far less surly and dysfunctional. So mitigating secular stagnation is of profound importance. Writing in 1930, in circumstances far more dire than those we face today, Keynes still managed to summon some optimism. Using a British term for a type of alternator in a car engine, he noted that the economy had what he called “magneto trouble.” A car with a broken alternator won’t move at all—yet it takes only a simple repair to get it going. In https://www.foreignaffairs.com/articles/china/2015-05-07/whos- afraid-aiib 3/14/2020 The Age of Secular Stagnation | Larry Summers larrysummers.com/2016/02/17/the-age-of-secular-stagnation/ 6/6 © LAWRENCE H. SUMMERS, 2019 much the same way, secular stagnation does not reveal a profound or inherent �aw in capitalism. Raising demand is actually not that di�cult, and it is much easier than raising the capacity to produce. The crucial thing is for policymakers to
  • 22. diagnose the problem correctly and make the appropriate repairs. Copyright © 2016 by the Council on Foreign Relations, Inc. All rights reserved. To request permission to distribute or reprint this article, please �ll out and submit a Permissions Request Form. If you plan to use this article in a coursepack or academic website, visit Copyright Clearance Center to clear permission. Source URL: https://www.foreigna�airs.com/articles/united- states/2016-02-15/age- secular-stagnation Links [1] https://www.foreigna�airs.com/reviews/2015-02-16/can- economists-learn [2] https://www.foreigna�airs.com/reviews/review- essay/second-great-depression [3] https://www.foreigna�airs.com/articles/united-states/2012- 04-23/all-presidents- central-bankers [4] https://www.foreigna�airs.com/articles/united-states/2011- 06-29/america-s-weak- recovery [5] http://www.economist.com/blogs/graphicdetail/2014/11/secular- stagnation-graphics [6] https://www.foreigna�airs.com/reviews/review-essay/2016- 01-28/innovation-over [7] http://www.brookings.edu/blogs/ben- bernanke/posts/2015/04/01-why-interest-rates- low-global-savings-glut [8] https://www.foreigna�airs.com/articles/china/2016-01- 11/end-chinas-rise
  • 23. [9] https://www.foreigna�airs.com/articles/2015-12-12/fourth- industrial-revolution [10] https://www.foreigna�airs.com/reviews/review- essay/thinkers-and-tinkerers [11] http://krugman.blogs.nytimes.com/2013/04/11/monetary- policy-in-a-liquidity-trap/? _r=0 [12] https://www.foreigna�airs.com/reviews/capsule- review/2007-05-01/milton- friedman-biography [13] https://www.foreigna�airs.com/articles/united-states/1979- 09-01/stag�ation-how- we-got-it-how-get-out [14] https://www.foreigna�airs.com/articles/china/2015-05- 07/whos-afraid-aiib https://www.youtube.com/channel/UCF_dVFHJjSCiUJVZdf7Hlf Q https://www.facebook.com/LarrySummers/ https://twitter.com/LHSummers http://www.foreignaffairs.com/permissions http://www.copyright.com/ https://www.foreignaffairs.com/articles/united-states/2016-02- 15/age-secular-stagnation https://www.foreignaffairs.com/reviews/2015-02-16/can- economists-learn https://www.foreignaffairs.com/reviews/review-essay/second- great-depression https://www.foreignaffairs.com/articles/united-states/2012-04- 23/all-presidents-central-bankers https://www.foreignaffairs.com/articles/united-states/2011-06- 29/america-s-weak-recovery http://www.economist.com/blogs/graphicdetail/2014/11/secular- stagnation-graphics https://www.foreignaffairs.com/reviews/review-essay/2016-01- 28/innovation-over
  • 24. … 1/22/2018 The Great Recession: A Macroeconomic Earthquake | Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis https://minneapolisfed.org/research/economic-policy- papers/the-great-recession-a-macroeconomic-earthquake 1/8 HOME CAREERS CONTACT Search Home > Economic Research > Economic Policy Papers > The Great Recession: A Macroeconomic Earthquake Economic Policy Papers RSS PDF Version TWEET SHARE POST EMAIL PRINT The Great Recession: A Macroeconomic Earthquake Why it happened, endured and wasn’t foreseen. And how it’s changing theory Lawrence J. Christiano | Consultant Published February 7, 2017 Economic Policy Papers are based on policy-oriented research produced by Minneapolis Fed staff and consultants. The papers are an occasional series for a general audience. The views expressed here are those of the authors, not necessarily those of others in the Federal Reserve System. Executive Summary The Great Recession was particularly severe and has endured
  • 25. far longer than most recessions. Economists now believe it was caused by a perfect storm of declining home prices, a financial system heavily invested in house-related assets and a shadow banking system highly vulnerable to bank runs or rollover risk. It has lasted longer than most recessions because economically damaged households were unwilling or unable to increase spending, thus perpetuating the recession by a mechanism known as the paradox of thrift. Economists believe the Great Recession wasn’t foreseen because the size and fragility of the shadow banking system had gone unnoticed. The recession has had an inordinate impact on macroeconomics as a discipline, leading economists to reconsider two largely discarded theories: IS-LM and the paradox of thrift. It has also forced theorists to better understand and incorporate the financial sector into their models, the most promising of which focus on mismatch between the maturity periods of assets and liabilities held by banks. Introduction Latest Content from the Minneapolis Fed Minneapolis Fed Releases Report on Early Childhood Development in Montana News Releases Slow Convergence in Economies with Organization Capital Working Paper
  • 26. Early Childhood Development in Montana Community Development Papers WSJ Op-Ed: Immigration Is Practically a Free Lunch for America Messages Equity and Efficiency in Space The Region Connect MinneapolisFed on Twitter Minneapolis Fed on Facebook RSS Feeds About the Fed Banking Supervision Economic Research Regional Economy Community & Education News & Events Publications https://minneapolisfed.org/ https://minneapolisfed.org/ https://minneapolisfed.org/about/careers https://minneapolisfed.org/forms/contact https://minneapolisfed.org/ https://minneapolisfed.org/research https://minneapolisfed.org/research/economic-policy-papers https://minneapolisfed.org/research/economic-policy-papers https://minneapolisfed.org/research/economic-policy-papers/rss https://minneapolisfed.org/research/economic-policy-papers/rss https://minneapolisfed.org/~/media/files/pubs/eppapers/17- 1/the-great-recession-a-macroeconomic-earthquake.pdf javascript:window.print() https://minneapolisfed.org/research/economic-policy-papers https://minneapolisfed.org/authors/lawrence-j-christiano
  • 27. https://minneapolisfed.org/research/economic-policy-papers https://minneapolisfed.org/news-and-events/news- releases/minneapolis-fed-releases-report-on-early-childhood- development-in-montana https://minneapolisfed.org/research/working-papers/slow- convergence-in-economies-with-organization-capital https://minneapolisfed.org/community/community-development- papers/early-childhood-development-in-montana https://minneapolisfed.org/news-and-events/messages/wsj-op- ed-immigration-is-practically-a-free-lunch-for-america https://minneapolisfed.org/publications/the-region/equity-and- efficiency-in-space http://www.twitter.com/minneapolisfed http://www.facebook.com/MinneapolisFed https://minneapolisfed.org/publications/subscriptions-rss-and- reader/rss https://minneapolisfed.org/about https://minneapolisfed.org/banking https://minneapolisfed.org/research https://minneapolisfed.org/economy https://minneapolisfed.org/community https://minneapolisfed.org/news-and-events https://minneapolisfed.org/publications 1/22/2018 The Great Recession: A Macroeconomic Earthquake | Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis https://minneapolisfed.org/research/economic-policy- papers/the-great-recession-a-macroeconomic-earthquake 2/8 The Great Recession struck individuals, the aggregate economy and the economics profession like an earthquake, and its aftershocks are still being felt. Job losses and housing foreclosures devastated many families. National economies were
  • 28. deeply damaged and have yet to fully recover. And economists— who failed to predict either the crisis or the recession— have been struggling to understand why they didn’t grasp the fragility of the financial system and the duration of the recession. This essay briefly discusses why the Great Recession is considered both “Great” and a “Recession.” It then turns to the emerging consensus about its cause, its duration and the reasons so few predicted it. Finally, it explores the impact of the Great Recession on how academic economists now think about the economy. “Great Recession” The economic downturn the United States suffered from late 2007 to the third quarter of 2009 was particularly damaging. Output, consumption, investment, employment and total hours worked dropped far more during the recent recession than the comparable average figures for all other recessions since 1945. Employment, for example, dropped 6.7 percent during the 2007- 09 recession compared with an average of 3.8 percent for postwar recessions. Analogous figures for output: 7.2 percent and 4.4 percent; for consumption: 5.4 percent and 2.1 percent. That higher level of severity across the board is why this recession has earned the adjective “Great.” By the same token, however, this recession was definitely not the worst U.S. downturn on record. Conditions were far worse during the Great Depression. Employment fell 27 percent from 1929 to
  • 29. 1933 (compared with 6.7 percent from 2007 to 2009), output fell 36 percent (7.2 percent) and consumption fell 23 percent (5.4 percent). For that reason, the recent slump, though severe, is rightly considered a recession rather than a full-bore depression. Another reason to consider this recession “Great” is how uncommonly long the economy has been taking to recover. The accompanying figure displays labor productivity (output per working-age person, adjusted for inflation) from 1977 through 2014. The vertical pink bars in the figure indicate the starting and ending dates for recessions, as determined by the National Bureau of Economic Research (NBER). 1 1/22/2018 The Great Recession: A Macroeconomic Earthquake | Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis https://minneapolisfed.org/research/economic-policy- papers/the-great-recession-a-macroeconomic-earthquake 3/8 The U.S. economy did not return to the 2007 level of output per capita until a little over five years later, in first quarter 2013. The productivity trend lines for the previous four recessions show that the economy usually snaps back more quickly. Even now, the U.S. economy is still about 10 percent below normal (that is, trend growth in 2007). What caused the Great Recession?
  • 30. Conventional wisdom is now converging on a particular narrative about the cause of the Great Recession. In effect, the Great Recession was a “perfect storm” created by the concurrence of three factors. Taken by itself, none of these factors would have caused a major recession, but in combination, they were explosive. The first was the decline in housing prices that began in the summer of 2007. Whether this was the end of a “bubble” or just an ordinary fluctuation does not matter for the narrative. The second factor was that the financial system was heavily invested in housing-related assets, mortgage-backed securities. The third factor was that the shadow banking system was invested in housing assets and highly vulnerable to bank runs. These three factors are the essential elements in the following narrative about the Great Recession. The fall in housing prices damaged the assets of the shadow banking system and thereby created the conditions in which a run on the shadow banking system could occur. Alas, a run did occur in the summer of 2007, forcing the shadow banking system to sell its assets at fire sale prices. This asset decline damaged the whole banking system and hindered its ability to intermediate not just house purchases, but investment more generally. With reduced credit, purchases of houses declined and the fall in house prices was reinforced. By reducing household wealth, the fall in house prices induced households to cut back on spending. Faced with declining sales, firms pulled back on investment and hiring. All of these factors
  • 31. reinforced each other, sending the economy into the tailspin documented above. 2 3 4 5 6 1/22/2018 The Great Recession: A Macroeconomic Earthquake | Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis https://minneapolisfed.org/research/economic-policy- papers/the-great-recession-a-macroeconomic-earthquake 4/8 Why has it lasted so long? The conventional view on why the recession lasted so long is that the events described in the previous paragraph reinforced the desire to save, relative to the desire to invest. If markets worked efficiently, then the interest rate would have fallen to balance the demand and supply of savings, without a significant fall in employment. According to the conventional view, this required that interest rates be substantially negative, something that could not be achieved because the nominal interest rate cannot be much below zero. Because interest rates could not fall enough to clear lending markets, something else had to bring the demand
  • 32. and supply of saving into equality. That something else was the fall in aggregate output and income, which allowed lending markets to clear by reducing saving as people tried to avoid reducing their consumption too much. This is essentially the logic of the “paradox of thrift” analyzed in undergraduate textbooks in macroeconomics. Consistent with those textbooks, the fall in output arising from this paradox-of-thrift reasoning could in principle last for a long time. Why didn’t policymakers or economists see it coming? The emerging consensus is that no one, neither policymakers nor academic economists, was aware of the third factor underlying the Great Recession, the size and fragility of the shadow banking sector (see, for example, Bernanke 2010). The reason is simple. Much of what policymakers and economists know about financial markets comes about as a side effect of regulation, and the shadow banking system existed mostly outside the normal regulatory framework. Impact on macroeconomics The Great Recession is having an enormous impact on macroeconomics as a discipline, in two ways. First, it is leading economists to reconsider two theories that had largely been discredited or neglected. Second, it has led the profession to find ways to incorporate the financial sector into macroeconomic theory. Neglected paradigms At its heart, the narrative described above characterizes the Great
  • 33. Recession as the response of the economy to a negative shock to the demand for goods all across the board. This is very much in the spirit of the traditional macroeconomic paradigm captured by the famous IS-LM (or Hicks-Hansen) model, which places demand shocks like this at the heart of its theory of business cycle fluctuations. Similarly, the paradox-of-thrift argument is also expressed naturally in the IS-LM model. The IS-LM paradigm, together with the paradox of thrift and the notion that a decision by a group of people could give rise to a welfare-reducing drop in output, had been largely discredited among professional macroeconomists since the 1980s. But the Great Recession seems impossible to understand without invoking paradox-of-thrift logic and appealing to shocks in aggregate demand. As a consequence, the modern equivalent of the IS-LM model—the New Keynesian model—has returned to center stage. (To be fair, the return of the IS-LM model began in 7 8 9 10 11 12 1/22/2018 The Great Recession: A Macroeconomic Earthquake |
  • 34. Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis https://minneapolisfed.org/research/economic-policy- papers/the-great-recession-a-macroeconomic-earthquake 5/8 the late 1990s, but the Great Recession dramatically accelerated the process.) The return of the dynamic version of the IS-LM model is revolutionary because that model is closely allied with the view that the economic system can sometimes become dysfunctional, necessitating some form of government intervention. This is a big shift from the dominant view in the macroeconomics profession in the wake of the costly high inflation of the 1970s. Because that inflation was viewed as a failure of policy, many economists in the 1980s were comfortable with models that imply markets work well by themselves and government intervention is typically unproductive. Accounting for the financial sector The Great Recession has had a second important effect on the practice of macroeconomics. Before the Great Recession, there was a consensus among professional macroeconomists that dysfunction in the financial sector could safely be ignored by macroeconomic theory. The idea was that what happens on Wall Street stays on Wall Street—that is, it has as little impact on the economy as what happens in Las Vegas casinos. This idea received support from the U.S. experiences in 1987 and the early 2000s, when the economy seemed unfazed by substantial stock market volatility. But the idea that financial markets could be ignored in macroeconomics died with the Great Recession.
  • 35. Now macroeconomists are actively thinking about the financial system, how it interacts with the broader economy and how it should be regulated. This has necessitated the construction of new models that incorporate finance, and the models that are empirically successful have generally integrated financial factors into a version of the New Keynesian model, for the reasons discussed above. (See, for example, Christiano, Motto and Rostagno 2014.) Economists have made much progress in this direction, too much to summarize in this brief essay. One particularly notable set of advances is seen in recent research by Mark Gertler, Nobuhiro Kiyotaki and Andrea Prestipino. (See Gertler and Kiyotaki 2015 and Gertler, Kiyotaki and Prestipino 2016.) In their models, banks finance long-term assets with short-term liabilities. This liquidity mismatch between assets and liabilities captures the essential reason that real world financial institutions are vulnerable to runs. As such, the model enables economists to think precisely about the narrative described above (and advocated by Bernanke 2010 and others) about what launched the Great Recession in 2007. Refining models of this kind is essential for understanding the root causes of severe economic downturns and for designing regulatory and other policies that can prevent a recurrence of disasters like the Great Recession. Endnotes 1 The output and population data were obtained from FRED, the online database maintained by the Federal Reserve Bank of St.
  • 36. Louis. The FRED label for the output measure is GDPC1, and the label for the working-age population is LFWA64TTUSQ647S. 1/22/2018 The Great Recession: A Macroeconomic Earthquake | Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis https://minneapolisfed.org/research/economic-policy- papers/the-great-recession-a-macroeconomic-earthquake 6/8 2 The exact amount of time required for per capita output to return to its prerecession peak depends somewhat on the population measure used. If instead the civilian non-institutional population measure (FRED label CNP16OV) were used, then the amount of time would have been longer, roughly seven years. The difference from the results in the figure reflects demographic factors that cause the working-age population to grow less rapidly than the population as a whole. 3 For additional discussion about the trend of U.S. economic output in 2007, see Christiano, Eichenbaum and Trabandt (2015). The 10 percent number in the text was rounded after doing the following calculations. I fit a linear time trend to the natural logarithm of the output measure in the figure, using data from the beginning of the sample to the fourth quarter of 2007, the quarter before the Great Recession began according to the NBER. I extended the trend to the end of the sample. The difference between the trend at the end of the sample and the (log of the)
  • 37. last data point is 0.136, which I rounded to 0.10. The 10 percent number reported in the text is the last number, multiplied by 100. 4 An early, subsequently discarded, view was the so-called labor mismatch hypothesis. It held that the low level of employment was not due to a lack of jobs, but to the lack of workers with the right skills to fill them. Workforce and firms were “mismatched.” This view lost its appeal as it became apparent just how broad- based the recession was. Employment and hours worked fell in virtually all sectors. The unemployment rate jumped for virtually every type of worker, by level of education and occupation. According to the mismatch hypothesis, wage growth should have been especially high and unemployment low for the highly sought- after types of workers. But jobs were scarce virtually everywhere, for everyone. Why did employers hire so few workers? Since the early 1970s, the National Federation of Independent Business has surveyed its members to find out what their top problem is. They are asked to select from among 10 possibilities, including taxes, inflation, poor sales and quality of labor. Under the mismatch hypothesis, a large fraction of firms should have selected “quality of labor” as their top
  • 38. problem. They didn’t. Instead, “poor sales” surged beyond all other options as their top problem. Firms were not hiring simply because people were not buying their goods and services. 5 It is an interesting story, beyond the scope of this analysis, how so much money came to be invested in mortgages. Under the conventional view, the source of the money was what Bernanke (2005) called the “savings glut”: Money poured in from high- saving countries in Asia and oil-producing regions. Under what Shin (2012) called the “banking glut,” a lot of that incoming money went to Europe and then came right back to the United States. The European institutions that managed this back-and-forth flow had a strong preference for mortgages. Evidence in favor of the notion that the large current account deficit reflected an increase in the supply of funds by foreigners is the sharp drop in interest rates since 2000. The evidence that a lot of the extra money went into mortgages is that mortgage rates and lending conditions became particularly loose. For further discussion of this view, see Justiniano, Primiceri and Tambalotti 1/22/2018 The Great Recession: A Macroeconomic Earthquake | Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis https://minneapolisfed.org/research/economic-policy- papers/the-great-recession-a-macroeconomic-earthquake 7/8 (2015). Evidence consistent with the notion that the U.S.
  • 39. current account deficit played an important role in housing markets can also be seen in the substantial covariation between U.S. housing prices and the current account (see Figure 1.1 in Justiano, Primiceri and Tambalotti 2015). 6 Technically, what happened was a rollover crisis, not a traditional bank run like those familiar from movies and photographs from the Great Depression. For a careful discussion of a rollover crisis, see Gertler and Kiyotaki (2015). 7 The paradox-of-thrift argument described in the text lies at the heart of the analysis of the interest rate lower bound in Eggertsson and Woodford (2003). 8 That shadow banking system was of a similar order of magnitude as the traditional banking system discussed in Geithner (2008). 9 The IS-LM model—often depicted graphically and thought to encapsulate traditional Keynesian theory—describes the relationship between real output (GDP) and nominal interest rates. On a graph with real interest rates on the vertical axis and real GDP on the horizontal, IS-LM is seen as a downward- sloping IS curve (investment and savings, or the market for economic goods) and an upward-sloping LM curve (liquidity preference and money supply). The intersection of these curves indicates an economy’s equilibrium interest rate and GDP. 10 This is the idea that if people feel poor because the economy is not prospering, they’ll cut back on spending; that cutback will, in turn, encourage businesses to retrench on investment and hiring,
  • 40. leading to a self-fulfilling prophecy of economic downturn. The “paradox” is that while thrift at the individual level may be wise, it can have a harmful impact on the broader economy and ultimately on individuals as well. See, for example, “Paradox” Redux in the June 2013 Region. 11 Businesses reducing investment when they experience lower sales, for instance, or households cutting back because they feel poor with the fall in house prices. 12 For another model that may also be able to come to terms with the data on the Great Recession, see Buera and Nicolini (2016). References Bernanke, Ben S. 2005. “The Global Saving Glut and the U.S. Current Account Deficit.” Sandridge Lecture. Virginia Association of Economists, April 14. Bernanke, Ben S. 2010. Statement before the Financial Crisis Inquiry Commission. Washington, D.C., Sept. 2. https://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/testimony/bernanke 20100902a.pdf Buera, Francisco and Juan Pablo Nicolini. 2016. “Liquidity Traps and Monetary Policy: Managing a Credit Crunch.” Unpublished manuscript, Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago. Christiano, Lawrence J., Martin S. Eichenbaum and Mathias Trabandt. 2015. “Understanding the Great Recession.”
  • 41. American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics 7 (1): 110-67. https://minneapolisfed.org/publications/the-region/paradox- redux https://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/testimony/bernanke 20100902a.pdf 1/22/2018 It Wasn't Household Debt That Caused the Great Recession - The Atlantic https://www.theatlantic.com/business/archive/2014/05/house-of- debt/371282/ 1/10 Like The Atlantic? Subscribe to The Atlantic Daily , our free weekday email newsletter. Email SIGN UP Why are nearly 10 million people still out of work today? Was it because in September 2008, the U.S. government failed to bail out the insolvent investment bank Lehmann Brothers? Was it because the two U.S. housing finance giants Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac guaranteed too many mortgages securitized by It Wasn't Household Debt That Caused the Great Recession
  • 42. It was how that debt was disproportionately distributed to America’s most economically fragile communities. HEATHER BOUSHEY MAY 21, 2014 | BUSINESS Reuters http://www.theatlantic.com/newsletters/daily/ https://www.theatlantic.com/author/heather-boushey/ https://www.theatlantic.com/business/ 1/22/2018 It Wasn't Household Debt That Caused the Great Recession - The Atlantic https://www.theatlantic.com/business/archive/2014/05/house-of- debt/371282/ 2/10 Lehman and other Wall Street firms to low-income borrowers in the run up to the housing and financial crises? Or does blame rest with the Federal Reserve’s too- easy-money policies in the wake of the brief dotcom recession in the early 2000s? Princeton University professor Atif Mian and University of Chicago Booth School of Business professor Amir Sufi pin the blame squarely on policymakers, but not for
  • 43. any of these three reasons, all of which are variously popular with policymakers on different sides of the political divide in Washington. Instead, in their just-released book, House of Debt, they argue that the Great Recession was the result of a sharp fall-off in consumption due to the unevenly accumulated household debt in the first six years of the 21st century. In that period, mortgage-credit grew more than twice as fast in neighborhoods with low credit scores than in neighborhoods with high credit scores, a marked departure from the experience of previous decades. When the housing bubble popped, the economic consequences were sharply magnified by the way debt was distributed across households and communities. How did this happen? Why did lenders suddenly shower less- creditworthy borrowers with trillions of dollars of credit? Mian and Sufi demonstrate this was enabled by the securitization of home mortgages by investment banks that did not
  • 44. seek federal guarantees from Fannie and Freddie—so called private-label securities, made possible by financial deregulation and the glut of cash in world markets in the wake of the Asian financial crisis of the late 1990s. That private- label mortgage-backed securities were at the core of the housing meltdown is no longer in doubt, but what Mian and Sufi bring to the debate is how an unequal distribution of debt magnified the economic risks—based on their path-breaking microeconomic research—and a new framework for considering who is to blame among policymakers for the still reverberating debacle. Unfortunately, the two authors don’t provide answers for why so many households took on so much debt, but they do paint a cautionary tale. This is a critically important contribution to the policy debate now raging over what Congress and the Obama administration should do in the way of reforms to the housing-finance industry. And, it’s important to our understanding of whether
  • 45. and how inequality http://www.amazon.com/House-Debt-Recession-Prevent- Happening/dp/022608194X 1/22/2018 It Wasn't Household Debt That Caused the Great Recession - The Atlantic https://www.theatlantic.com/business/archive/2014/05/house-of- debt/371282/ 3/10 affects economic growth and stability. What they demonstrate is that as the U.S. housing bubble burst and home prices began to fall in late 2006, the unequal distribution of debt amplified the decline in consumer spending and the consequence was an economic disaster. Mian and Sufi’s research leads them to conclude that the crisis was avoidable if only economists had used the right framework to see what was happening around them at the time. “Economic disasters are man-made,” they write in the opening pages, “and the right framework can help us understand how to prevent them.” By the end of the book, the reader cannot but be left appalled at the sheer
  • 46. enormity of the policy failures. It’s not just that 7.4 million workers lost their job during the years of the Great Recession of 2007-2009 but also that the employment crisis continues to this day. While jobs are no longer being shed at the rate of 20,000 a day, the share of the U.S. population with a job fell to a low of 58.2 percent in November 2010 from a high of 63.4 percent in December 2006, but has only increased by a fraction of a percentage since then, hitting just 58.9 percent in April 2014. Missing the housing bubble was a massive failure on the part of policymakers. As a result, our new normal is one where there are nearly 10 million fewer people at work. This book's contribution helps us understand the important mechanisms through which this occurred. * * * I watched the housing and financial crises unfold from my perch as staff for the U.S.
  • 47. Congressional Joint Economic Committee. By the time Lehman Brothers failed, the mantra on Capitol Hill had been articulated by former Treasury Secretary Lawrence Summers, who said that any recovery package had to be “timely, targeted, and temporary.” But the stimulus that emerged was not specifically targeted at homeowners in foreclosure. If Mian and Sufi are correct, the biggest failure was—and continues to be—leaving families struggling with mortgages they cannot afford because of the fall in home prices. http://www.nytimes.com/roomfordebate/2014/05/20/did-the- bank-bailout-do-enough-for-the-country 1/22/2018 It Wasn't Household Debt That Caused the Great Recession - The Atlantic https://www.theatlantic.com/business/archive/2014/05/house-of- debt/371282/ 4/10 The federal government has provided assistance to a paltry 940,000 struggling homeowners through the Homeowners Assistance Mortgage Program, in a nation where 5 million homes have been foreclosed on. This lack of
  • 48. help hasn’t just hurt those homeowners. Also caught in the downdraft are now destroyed neighborhoods, ruined communities, and thwarted lives of far too many. Protecting banks does not necessarily make the economy strong. So, how did we get here? That’s the focus of House of Debt. Mian and Sufi spent the past decade compiling and analyzing microeconomic data to test theories about how the macroeconomy works. They conclude that inequality in wealth and debt combined with greater availability of credit to marginal borrowers are a toxic macro-economic combination. They call this the “levered losses” view, arguing that severe recessions occur when “asset prices collapse and households sharply pull back on spending,” even with “no obvious destruction of productive capacity occurs." Their story starts with an accumulation of debt—lots of it. After the Asian financial
  • 49. crisis in 1997, investors were looking for safe havens to park their money. What they wanted were AAA-rated bonds. What they got were mortgage-backed securities that were rated AAA but turned out to be junk. As we all now know—but most of us didn’t know at the time—Wall Street firms in the early 2000s began slicing and dicing and then reassembling mortgage debt into more and more exotic and risky mortgage-backed securities in ways that made them look risk-free. If debt had been more equally distributed then the decline in consumption would have been less dramatic and the recession would have been less devastating. But, it wasn’t just that there was more securitization. It was that loans made to riskier borrowers were more likely to be securitized. This both drove the housing bubble and made the consequences of it popping all the worse. Mian and Sufi point out that between 2002 and 2005, the growth in mortgage credit and household
  • 50. 1/22/2018 It Wasn't Household Debt That Caused the Great Recession - The Atlantic https://www.theatlantic.com/business/archive/2014/05/house-of- debt/371282/ 5/10 incomes became negatively correlated, that is, credit expanded in areas where incomes were declining. This makes no sense: How can you pay back a loan if your income is falling? They point to academic research by Yuliya Demyanyk and Otto Van Hemert showing the profound consequences: By 2006, loans had become so disconnected from prudent business practices that “an unusually large fraction of subprime mortgages originated in 2006 and 2007 [became] delinquent or in foreclosure only months later.” As these foreclosures began to pile up, affected households cut back sharply on spending. Thus, the catalyst for Great Recession had begun two years before the dramatic demise of Lehman Brothers. In the second quarter of 2006, the collapse in consumption started with residential investment, which fell
  • 51. by a 17 percent annual rate. Non-residential investment didn’t begin to fall until late in 2008, but by then households had already pared back spending sharply. This fallout from the collapse of the housing bubble was amplified by the unequal distribution of net wealth. What Mian and Sufi find is that counties with the largest decline in total net worth—were the ones that cut back most on spending when house prices declined. As housing prices began falling in 2006, in counties where net worth had declined most, consumption fell by almost 20 percent, compared to only five percent for the entire U.S. economy. In contrast, even through 2008, counties that avoided the collapse in net worth saw almost no decline in spending. If debt had been more equally distributed then the decline in consumption would have been less dramatic and the recession would have been less devastating. Mian and Sufi are part of a new generation of economists who examine detailed microeconomic data to understand
  • 52. the macroeconomy, giving us a deeper understanding of how inequality affects growth and stability. Further, they point out that you cannot have a foreclosure crisis—or its associated sharp fall-off in demand—without debt and the way that debt grew during the early 2000s exacerbated the potential for a foreclosure crisis. Mian and Sufi find that 1/22/2018 It Wasn't Household Debt That Caused the Great Recession - The Atlantic https://www.theatlantic.com/business/archive/2014/05/house-of- debt/371282/ 6/10 about half of the rise in mortgage debt was among people who lived in their homes, not new purchasers. People took out home equity lines of credit and used the cash for home improvements, funds for their kids' college tuition, or other types of consumption. Once the crisis was in motion, about four-in-10 mortgage defaults were among home-equity borrowers. Thus, the foreclosure crisis was not due to people reaching to buy homes, but to borrowing against their
  • 53. primary asset. Had they not ramped up borrowing, falling home prices would not have affected consumption or led to record-high foreclosures. Finally, all this subprime mortgage debt that had been structured into AAA-rated mortgage-backed securities created financial instruments in which no single investor has the incentive or legal right to restructure the loan, especially for loans to low-net-worth borrowers. This led to a situation that dramatically reduced the capacity of homeowners to get relief in form or informal backruptcy and increased foreclosures. Foreclosures reduce prices more so than principal reductions and thus amplified the decline in home prices and the loss in wealth. * * * Given the troubling rise in economic inequality over the past four decades, this research could not be more timely. It’s not just the questions they are asking and the results they are finding, but also the methods they are using.
  • 54. Mian and Sufi are part of a new generation of economists who examine detailed microeconomic data and analysis to understand the macroeconomy, giving us a deeper understanding of how inequality affects economic growth and stability. They have done this by using detailed, microeconomic data at the county and zip-code level to examine debt and consumption patterns. Mian and Sufi’s research shows that the marginal propensity to consume—an economics term that describes the amount of spending done after receiving an additional dollar—out of housing wealth depends not just on the value of the asset but also the debt burden, settling a near-century-old economic debate between two of the most prominent economists of the 20th century. 1/22/2018 It Wasn't Household Debt That Caused the Great Recession - The Atlantic https://www.theatlantic.com/business/archive/2014/05/house-of-
  • 55. debt/371282/ 7/10 In The General Theory of Employment, Interests, and Money, University of Cambridge economist John Maynard Keynes argued in 1936 that the distribution of income mattered for the stability of the macroeconomy. Increased spending, be it from consumers, government, greater exports, or investment, will multiply as it works its way through the economy. If additional income goes into the hands of those with a high marginal propensity to consume then the multiplier for consumption demand will be relatively larger. But if additional income goes into the hands of those with a lower marginal propensity to consume then the multiplier on consumption demand will be relatively weaker. Two decades later, University of Chicago economist Milton Friedman hypothesized that although rich households appear to consume less, they have a pretty clear sense of what their standard of living will be on average year after year
  • 56. and they adjust their savings to keep themselves at that level. In good years, when they get an income bonus, they will save a more while in bad years, they won’t save as much—or will borrow—to maintain that average standard of living. Yet neither Keynes nor Friedman had access to the kinds of data now at the fingertips of Mian and Sufi. Thus the Keynes-Friedman debate was theoretical, not grounded in empirical reality. Now, Mian and Sufi provide a definite “yes” to the question of whether we could have prevented the Great Recession—and the conclusion isn’t pretty. They argue that policymakers could have seriously mitigated the damage, pointing out that debt forgiveness would have been much more effective that the policies implemented because it would have targeted households with the largest marginal propensity to consume. This is a failure on a massive scale and more economists need to follow the lead of Mian and Sufi and
  • 57. look deep into the data to understand what we got wrong. Mian and Sufi’s argument hinges on the conclusion that it was the supply of credit that drove the bubble and the heightened debt burdens, rather than increased demand from consumers. They discuss some reasons why people may have wanted to borrow more, such as the idea that people who expected higher incomes were borrowing constrained, but come down on the side that people were just acting 1/22/2018 It Wasn't Household Debt That Caused the Great Recession - The Atlantic https://www.theatlantic.com/business/archive/2014/05/house-of- debt/371282/ 8/10 irrationally—given that the massive increase in borrows during the credit boom was among borrowers with declining incomes, not those with rising incomes. From this, they conclude that “whatever the reason, however, consumers who were offered more money by lenders took it.”
  • 58. Were people behaving irrationally? And, what (really) does that mean? The late 1990s saw the strongest labor market in decades. The typical male earner saw his annual earnings finally grow, after over a decade-and-a-half of inflation-adjusted declines; women’s employment rates hit an all-time high of 58 percent; and the typical family income grew by an average annual rate of just under 2 percent. The middle was (finally) back, so it may have been the case that people were optimistic that the recession of 2001 would not just be short and shallow, but that the recovery would look like the late 1990s. But looking closely at the data reveals another pattern. One thing that did not happen during the recession of the early 2000s was a rise in government borrowing. The cash seeking a safe haven from the Asian financial crisis had to go somewhere, but the federal government wasn’t in the mood to borrow. So those
  • 59. dollars flowed willingly into the mortgage-backed securities being peddled as AAA- rated bonds. And the greater the demand, the more Wall Street packaged up their dodgy securities containing more and more subprime loans extended to those least able to afford credit. The last few decades of the 2oth century also saw a number of marked changes for families. Women increased their labor supply steadily from the 1960s through the high employment years of the early 1990s. By the late 1990s, however, that long- term rise in employment rates had stalled. The United States went from being an economy that had one of the largest shares of women in the labor force to number 18 among 35 developed-economy member nations of the Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development. A variety of reasons have been presented for the sudden end in the growth of women’s employment beginning in the first decade of the 21st century and
  • 60. continuing today. The mainstream media play up the idea that women are “opting 1/22/2018 It Wasn't Household Debt That Caused the Great Recession - The Atlantic https://www.theatlantic.com/business/archive/2014/05/house-of- debt/371282/ 9/10 out” of careers in favor of motherhood, a story line developed in large part by journalists who either live in more wealthy neighborhoods and thus see this happening or write for publications that cater mostly to these wealthy neighborhoods. Yet empirical research finds that women, like men, found it harder to find and keep jobs due to the lackluster economic recovery after the recession of 2001. As families sought to cope with the slow-job growth economy in the 2000s and a labor market that still does not provide the kinds of supports and protections working parents need, many turned to increasingly-readily- available credit as a way
  • 61. to cope. Now, of course, such easy credit is no longer available. Neither is a robust jobs market. It may be true that it doesn’t matter why people took on more debt prior to the Great Recession, as Mian and Sufi contend, but today the lessons learned then are critically important. The story that emerged in the early days of the Great Recession was that too many people borrowed too much to afford fancy houses. That’s not what Mian and Sufi’s data show. They show that the boom in debt occurred among borrowers that couldn’t qualify for a government-backed mortgage. That the private sector sought them out in the tens of millions to offer loans they were demonstrably unable to repay—without worry because these lenders very quickly diced up those loans and sold them to supposedly savvy institutional investors—created the housing bubble that exploded into the twin crises that led to the Great Recession.
  • 62. This activity produced a bubble—one that anyone could see and one that policymakers blithely passed off as either non-existent or unimportant—to the detriment of our entire economy. Subsequent reforms to our financial system give policymakers more tools to police housing finance, yet the continuing over-reliance on debt and a lack of good jobs leaves families at risk and exposes our economy to the whipsaw of another debt-fueled credit bubble. Mian and Sufi deserve credit of another kind for detailing how ensnared the American Dream is in this tangled web of debt finance—and how exposed the vast majority of us are to the broader economic consequences. ABOUT THE AUTHOR 1/22/2018 It Wasn't Household Debt That Caused the Great Recession - The Atlantic https://www.theatlantic.com/business/archive/2014/05/house-of- debt/371282/ 10/10
  • 63. HEATHER BOUSHEY is the executive director and chief economist at the Washington Center for Equitable Growth. https://www.theatlantic.com/author/heather-boushey/ http://equitablegrowth.org/ The topic will be Secular Stagnation. Details below: Topic: Did the “Great Recession” Lead to Secular Stagnation and How Should Policy Respond? Your assignment is to write an essay that analyzes the debate about secular stagnation in the aftermath of the Great Recession and to recommend policies in a way that is consistent with your diagnosis of the current situation. A complete assessment of the secular stagnation debate requires an understanding of how the economy got into this situation. Therefore, your essay should discuss the sources of the Great Recession and explain why some economists argue that the crisis led to secular stagnation. Your analysis should cover different sides of the debate, but it should lead to a clear statement of your own view about how the stagnation concept does or does not apply to the current state of U.S. economy. Based on this opinion, discuss the best path forward for economic policy. You need to consider the following concepts and questions: · What was the source of the Great Recession and how did it lead to the possibility of secular stagnation? · Link your analysis of what has happened with the Classical and Keynesian macroeconomic perspectives. Discuss how aspects of these theories are (or are not) helpful in explaining the relevant history. Also, your grade will be better if you can build a somewhat nuanced story that demonstrates a deep understanding of the theories. · When discussing secular stagnation directly, I encourage you to consider ways in which the recent recovery has been different from what happened after earlier recessions.
  • 64. · Link your policy recommendations in a consistent way to your theoretical and empirical understanding of the secular stagnation debate. Consider how both fiscal and monetary policy could improve the U.S. economy over the next few years. You should use the readings below to help guide your thinking about the essay. You may use outside resources, but it is not necessary to do outside research that goes beyond the readings. The target length of the essay is 2,500 words (approximately 5 pages single spaced). Please use 12 point, Times New Roman font.