SlideShare a Scribd company logo
1 of 64
Financial Regulation Lecture 9
Based on notes by Marlena Eley
March 22, 2019
1
1 Concept Review
We have been studying Cooper and Ross’s paper, which
demonstrates how
deposit insurance causes moral hazard. Their work uses the
Diamond and
Dybvig model and adds:
1. Risky Technology
2. Monitoring by Households (HH)
The introduction of deposit insurance reduces HH’s incentives
to monitor.
HHs would have to pay a fixed cost Γ, which is measured in
utils (an effort
cost rather than a resource cost), to monitor the bank. When
HHs do monitor,
they are able to FORCE the bank to invest in the safe
technology. We know
that HHs always prefer the safe long term technology
investment to the risky
technology investment because they are risk averse (u′′ < 0).
1.1 LEMMA
Let q denote the probability of a run - this q is exogenously
given. A Bank
that maximizes HH’s utility solves the following problem:
if q ≤ q∗ the deposit contract offered allows runs
if q > q∗ the deposit contract offered is a run preventing
contract
When q ≤ q∗ , banks are providing liquidity insurance, cE > 1,
which means
that a run is a potential equilibria. When q > q∗ , banks provide
contracts
similar to autarky allocations, cE = 1,cL = R.
Intuitively, if runs are not very likely, then the bank prefers to
offer a contract
that allows for runs but offers some liquidity insurance, which
is valuable to
households.
We’re studying when q ≤ q∗ because we want deposit insurance
to be offered
so that moral hazard is an issue.
1.2 Risky Technology
Risky technology is defined as:
(−1, 0,
{
λR with probability ν
0 with probability 1 −ν
Where:
1. λ > 1
2. νλ ≤ 1
2
Sidenote: when νλ = 1, we say this technology has a mean
preserving spread.
Moral hazard is introduced here and this implies that rather than
strictly
maximizing HH’s utility, Banks are now maximizing profit. The
“managers” of
the Banks get whatever is leftover after feeding the consumers.
Banks then maximize profit as follows:
max
i∈ [0,1]
ν[iλR + (1 − i−πcE)R− (1 −π)cL]
+ (1 −ν)max(i∗ 0 + (1 − i−πcE)R− (1 −π)cL, 0)
We see that the objective function is linear in i which tells us
that there may
be corner solutions where i∗ = 0 (investment is only made in
the safe
technology) or i∗ = 1 (investment is only made in the risky
technology).
1.3 The Threshold ī
We study this decision by establishing a threshold of
indifference, ī - when
they are indifferent between investing everything in the risky
technology and
investing in the safe technology.
We can establish ī by looking at the investment decision in the
low state,
(1 −ν) when the risky technology fails.
Conditional on being in the low state (1 −ν):
ī = {i ∈ [0, 1] : (1 − i−πcE)R− (1 −π)cL = 0}
∀i > ī, (1 − i−πcE)R− (1 −π)cL < 0, max = 0 therefore invests in
risky.
∀ i < ī, (1 − i−πcE)R− (1 −π)cL > 0, max = (1 − i−πcE)R− (1
−π)cL therefore invests in safe.
Our next step is to plug these values back into the objective
function for each
case.
If i ≥ ī, hence the max = 0, then the objective function becomes:
ν[iλR + (1 − i−πcE)R− (1 −π)cL] which is increasing in i
⇒ i∗ = 1
If i < ī, max = (1− i−πcE)R−(1−π)cL and the objective function
becomes:
ν[iλR + (1 − i−πcE)R− (1 −π)cL] + (1 −ν)[(1 − i−πcE)R− (1
−π)cL]
νiλR + (1 − i−πcE)R− (1 −π)cL which is decreasing in i
⇒ i∗ = 0
Now, we need to know which investment strategy results in the
higher profit
and therefore which investment strategy will be picked?
3
1.3.1 i∗ = 0
Well when i∗ = 0, the profit becomes: (1 −πcE) − (1 −π)cL.
We have been solving the Bank’s problem under the assumption
that they
would be offering the First Best contracts of c
sp
E and c
sp
L . We know at the First
Best the resource constraint faced by the Social Planner
resembles very closely
(exactly) the profit of the bank. The resource constraint being:
(1 −π)cL = (1 −πcE)R. This then tells us the the Bank’s profit
will be 0
when i∗ = 0!
1.3.2 i∗ = 1
Now we have to evaluate the profit when i∗ = 1, which is
νλR−πcER− (1 −π)cL. Again, part of this profit, πcER− (1
−π)cL
resembles very closely, actually exactly, the Resource
Constraint faced by the
Social Planner at the First Best solution, where (1 −π)cL = (1
−πcE)R. This
then tells us the profit when i∗ = 1 is νλR, which we know is
greater than 0!
Comparing these two profits, we know that the Bank will invest
in the risky
technology for the larger profit! This is the risky technology, so
i∗ = 1.
2 Monitoring
Given what we know:
1. δ = (cE,cL) is the first best allocation and
2. I(cE) and I(cL) are the deposit insurances offered if the bank
fails in t=1
and t=2, respectively
If the bank is investing in the safe technology, HH won’t
monitor. Why would
they pay the fixed cost Γ if they know they will get the safe
payout?
Given we know that the Bank will invest in the risky asset
(which we proved
in part 1), we want to find the Γ for which a HH will choose to
monitor.
Remember, by monitoring, HH FORCE the Bank to invest in the
safe
technology. We can find the Γ for which HH will monitor by
finding the
following:
EUtility without monitoring < E Utility with monitoring
2.1 E (Utility without monitoring)
The Expected utility without monitoring is as below:
π{(1 −q)[U(cL) + qU(I(cE))}+
(1 −π){[νU(cL) + (1 −ν)U(I(cL))] + qU(I(cE))
Broken down we have:
4
1. π{(1 −q)U(cE) + qU(I(cE))}, which is the expected utility of
impatient
agents. This multiplies π, the fraction of impatient agents by (1
−q), the
probability of no run, times the utility they would get in this
equilibria,
U(cE), plus q, the probability of a run times the utility they
would get in a
run U(I(cE)).
2.(1 −π){1 −q)[νU(cL) + (1 −ν)U(I(cL))] + qU(I(cE)), the
expected utility of
patient agents. This multiplies (1 −π), the fraction of patient
agents, by
(1 −q), the probability of no run, by the payoff received in no
run which is
νU(cL) + (1 −ν)U(I(cL)), which itself is an expectation of the
payoff based on
the success or failure of the risky technology, and q, the
probability of a run in
t = 1, multiplied by U(I(cE)).
2.2 E(Utility with monitoring)
The expected utility with monitoring is as below:
−Γ + [π((1 −q)U(cE) + q(I(cE)))] + (1 −π)[(1 −q)U(cL) +
qU(I(cE))]
Remember, by monitoring and incurring the effort cost Γ, HH
force the Bank
to invest in safe technology so we don’t even consider payoffs
of risky
technologies!
Broken down we have:
1. π((1 −q)U(cE) + q(I(cE))), which is the utility of impatient
agents and
2. (1 −π)[(1 −q)U(cL) + qU(I(cE)), the utility of patient agents.
2.3 E(Utility without monitoring) < E (Utility with
monitoring)
This inequality is as below:
π{(1 −q)[U(cE) + qU(I(cE))} + (1 −π){(1 −q)[νU(cL) + (1
−ν)U(I(cL))] +
qU(I(cE))}≤−Γ+[π((1−q)U(cE)+q(I(cE)))]+(1−π)[(1−q)U(cL)+q
U(I(cE))]
This equation greatly simplifies, namely terms for early
consumers cancel out,
which makes sense as they withdraw at t = 1 anyway so they
don’t care about
whether the bank invests in the risk technology (they are not
around at t = 2
anyway as they consume before and their preferences are not
defined over
consumption at t = 2). 1 In other words, if the bank invests in
risky
technologies, they are not the ones who face an insolvent bank.
This then simplifies to:
(1 −π){(1 −q)[νU(cL) + (1 −ν)U(I(cL))]}≤−Γ{(1 −π)[(1
−q)U(cL)]}
⇒ Γ ≤ (1 −π)(1 −q)(1 −ν)[U(cL) −U(I(cL))]
Here the tradeoff between deposit insurance and monitoring is
greatly
apparent, look at the term U(cL) −U(I(cL))!
1This is equivalent to saying they exit the economy, for our
purposes.
5
So far, we have been considering deposit insurance to be
complete, that is that
I(cL) = cL. If this is the case then,
Γ < 0 for HH to monitor the banks!
Therefore monitor will never take place under complete deposit
insurance for
any value of Γ > 0.
2.4 Finding Γ
Well, lets try to figure out if there is a way to have HH monitor
AND still
implement the First Best allocation.
Let’s consider the assumptions that we’re making:
1. cL = c
sp
L
2. If there was no insurance at all monitoring would take place
if we make
the following assumption:
Γ ≤ (1 −π)(1 −q)(1 −ν)U(cspL )
Now we have to consider whether we can implement the first
best allocation.
Well, if we do, there is a potential for a run equilibrium and HH
will monitor.
But by monitoring, HH incur the cost Γ and there is a potential
for a run.
Well, what happens with complete deposit insurance? HH don’t
monitor and
Banks end up investing in risky technology. HH are paid even in
the event of a
run or a Bank failure. Can the First Best be implemented in this
situation?
The solution offered by Cooper and Ross is Capital
Requirements. They
suggest that if Banks are solely gambling with depositors money
what would
happen if Banks were forced to invest some of their own
resources?
3 Capital Requirements
In the case of Capital Requirements we have to make an
additional
assumption.
1. Banks’ shareholders have ”deep pockets”
This just says that Banks get some money from outside the
model. These
shareholders have a large endowment of the good.
Cooper and Ross then introduce Capital Requirements which
require banks
to invest at least K units of their own endowment per unit of
deposit. With
the introduction of Capital Requirements the Banks problem
becomes:
max
i∈ [0,1+K]
{ν[iλR + (1 + K − i−πcE)R− (1 −π)cL]
+ (1 −ν)max((1 + K − i−πcE)R− (1 −π)cL, 0)}
6
We solve this the exact same way that we solved the previous
problem!
∀ī ∈ [0, 1 + K] such that the payoff in the low state is the same
regardless
whether the bank is solvent or not.
(1 + K − ī−πcE)R− (1 −π)cL = 0
∀ (1 + K − ī−πcE)R = (1 −πcL)
For i ≥ ī: max (1 + K − ī−πcE)R− (1 −π)cL, 0) = 0
⇒ i∗ = 1 + K (invest in the risky technology)
For i ≤ ī ⇒ i∗ = 0 (invest only in the safe technology)
The question then becomes, is there a value of K such that the
First Best
allocation can be implemented as an equilibrium outcome?
3.1 Finding K
There are three steps to finding this K:
1. Use the First Best allocation
2. Evaluate the Bank’s profit from investing all in safe or all in
risky
technology
3. Solve for the smallest K such that i = 0 (investment in all
safe
technology) yields the highest profit.
Solving for K in this way is solving for the minimum capital
requirement
necessary for the bank to be indifferent between investing in
risky technologies
and safe technologies. We know how to solve this: we evaluate
the investment
strategies at the two corners!
Step 1 - First Best Allocation
c
sp
E > 1 ⇒ c
sp
L < R
From the resource constraint at the First Best, (1 −π)cspL = R(1
−πc
sp
E )
Step 2 - The Bank’s Payoffs
max
i∈ [0,1+K]
ν[iλR + (1 + K − i−πcE)R− (1 −π)cL]
+ (1 −ν)max((1 + K − i−πcE)R− (1 −π)cL, 0)
Plugging in the Resource Constraint for (1 −π)cL = R(1 −πcE),
this
simplifies to:
max
i∈ [0,1+K]
{ν[iλR + (K − i)R] + (1 −ν)max((K − i)R, 0)}
The payoff at i = 0 is then KR.
The payoff at i = 1 + K is then ν[(1 + K)λR−R].
7
Step 3 - Finding the Smallest K
This then sets us up with the inequality KR ≥ ν[(1 + K)λR−R],
from which
we can solve for a K.
KR = ν[(1 + K)λR−R]
KR = ν(1 + K)λR−νR
K = νλ + νKλ−ν
K −νλK = νλ−ν
K(1 −νλ) = ν(λ− 1)
∴ K =
ν(λ− 1)
(1 −νλ)
For K =
ν(λ−1)
(1−νλ) , there is no monitoring AND we are implementing the
First
Best allocation! We are disciplining the moral hazard by
implementing these
Capital Requirements.
Because we know what λ and ν are, we can talk about how K
changes when
the technology becomes riskier.
3.2 How K Changes with λ and ν
If we assume that the risky technology has a mean preserving
spread, i.e.
λ̂ν̂ = λν and λ̂ > λ (the technology has higher returns) and ν̂ < ν
(the
technology has a lower probability of success), then:
K
̂ = ν̂λ̂−ν̂
1−ν̂λ̂
= λν−ν̂
1−λν ∀ K
̂ > K
This tells us that the riskier the technology, the higher the
capital requirement
needed to discipline the moral hazard and implement the First
Best allocation.
8
Institute of Social and Economic Research, Osaka University
Bank Runs: Deposit Insurance and Capital Requirements
Author(s): Russell Cooper and Thomas W. Ross
Source: International Economic Review, Vol. 43, No. 1 (Feb.,
2002), pp. 55-72
Published by: Wiley for the Economics Department of the
University of Pennsylvania and
Institute of Social and Economic Research, Osaka University
Stable URL: https://www.jstor.org/stable/827056
Accessed: 30-03-2019 02:57 UTC
JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars,
researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide
range of content in a trusted digital archive. We use information
technology and tools to increase productivity and
facilitate new forms of scholarship. For more information about
JSTOR, please contact [email protected]
Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the
Terms & Conditions of Use, available at
https://about.jstor.org/terms
Wiley, Institute of Social and Economic Research, Osaka
University are collaborating
with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend access to
International Economic Review
This content downloaded from 141.161.91.14 on Sat, 30 Mar
2019 02:57:00 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
INTERNATIONAL ECONOMIC REVIEW
Vol. 43, No. 1, February 2002
BANK RUNS: DEPOSIT INSURANCE AND CAPITAL
REQUIREMENTS*
BY RUSSELL COOPER AND THOMAS W. ROSS1
Boston University, U.S.A. and University of British Columbia,
Canada
Diamond and Dybvig provide a model of intermediation in
which deposit
insurance can avoid socially undesirable bank runs. We extend
the Diamond-
Dybvig model to evaluate the costs and benefits of deposit
insurance in the
presence of moral hazard by banks and monitoring by
depositors. We find that
complete deposit insurance alone will not support the first-best
outcome: de-
positors will not have adequate incentives for monitoring and
banks will invest
in excessively risky projects. However, an additional capital
requirement for
banks can restore the first-best allocation.
1. INTRODUCTION
The publicly supported deposit insurance plans of a number of
countries, most
notably the United States and Canada, have recently come
under intense public
scrutiny as concerns have mounted about the substantial
contingent liabilities they
have created for taxpayers. In the United States the savings and
loan (S&L) crisis led
to the transfer of a huge amount of bad debt, estimated recently
at about $130
billion, onto taxpayers' shoulders.2 Created originally to
support the banking sector
by building depositor confidence, there is recognition that the
insurance provided by
* Manuscript received November 1998; revised October 1999.
1This is a considerably expanded version of Section IV of our
NBER Working Paper, #3921,
November 1991. We have benefited from discussions on this
topic with Paul Beaudry, Fanny Demers,
Jon Eaton, Alok Johri, Arthur Rolnick, Thomas Rymes, Fabio
Schiantarelli, David Weil, and Steven
Williamson, and from helpful comments received from seminar
participants at Boston University,
Brown University, Carleton University, the Federal Reserve
Bank of Minneapolis, the University of
British Columbia, and the University of Maryland. The
extensive comments provided by three
referees and the editor of this journal are gratefully
acknowledged. Financial support for this work
came from the National Science Foundation, the SFU-UBC
Centre for the Study of Government and
Business, and the Social Sciences and Humanities Research
Council of Canada. The first author is
grateful to the Institute for Empirical Macroeconomics at the
Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis
for providing a productive working environment during
preparation of parts of this manuscript. Some
of this work was done while the second author was visiting the
Canadian Competition Bureau and he
is grateful for the Bureau's assistance. The views expressed
here are not necessarily those of the
Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis or of the Canadian
Competition Bureau. Please address
correspondence to: Russell Cooper, Department of Economics,
Boston University, 270 Bay State
Road, Boston, MA 02215. Fax: 617-353-4449. E-mail:
[email protected]
2 There is a considerable literature on the S&L crisis; see, for
example, Feldstein (1991),
Kormendi et al. (1989), and White (1991).
55
This content downloaded from 141.161.91.14 on Sat, 30 Mar
2019 02:57:00 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
COOPER AND ROSS
these plans has encouraged excessive risk taking by financial
intermediaries.3 These
concerns have led to calls for the reform of deposit insurance
and even suggestions
that it be abolished.
This paper attempts to evaluate the trade-offs between risk
sharing and moral
hazard associated with the design of banking regulations. In
particular, we focus on two
policy instruments: deposit insurance and bank capital
requirements. We are interested
in how these instruments can be used (and misused) to control
bank runs in an envi-
ronment in which banks can make imprudent investments and
depositors can monitor
bank behavior.
Reflecting ongoing problems in the financial services sector,
there has been a great
deal of research recently on lending behavior, bank stability,
and optimal banking
regulation. While a number of publications have considered
parts of the problem
addressed here, no individual contribution tackles the joint
determination of optimal
deposit insurance and capital requirements within a bank runs
model with risk-
averse depositors, depositor monitoring, and moral hazard.4
Given the ongoing
public debate over deposit insurance and capital requirements
and the attention paid
to the supposed trade-off between bank runs and moral hazard,
a structure is needed
that contains these elements.
With its emphasis on bank runs, the model of Diamond and
Dybvig (1983) provides a
convenient starting point for studying these issues. In the
absence of any moral hazard
considerations, Diamond and Dybvig argue that publicly
provided deposit insurance
can be effective as protection against expectations-driven bank
runs.5 However, their
3 Deposit insurance was created in the United States during the
Great Depression (1934) to
restore depositor confidence. It came to Canada in 1967.
Concerns about the Canadian system are
expressed in Smith and White (1988).
4 Some of this literature is reviewed in the recent books by
Dewatripont and Tirole (1994) and
Freixas and Rochet (1997). The articles closest in purpose to
this one include Giammarino et al.
(1993), Matutes and Vives (1996), Besanko and Kanatas
(1993), Holmstrom and Tirole (1993),
Kupiec and O'Brien (1997), and Peck and Shell (1999). Each
considers some aspect of our problem,
but none combines the elements we view as important here. For
example, Giammarino et al. (1993)
consider optimal deposit insurance premia in markets with bank
moral hazard but no bank runs.
Matutes and Vives (1996) study the effect of competition on
bank fragility with deposit insurance.
Besanko and Kanatas (1993) consider the provision of funds to
firms from both banks (through
loans) and capital markets in a model with bank moral hazard
but no bank runs. Studying bank
lending behavior (without deposits or bank runs), Holmstrom
and Tirole (1993) find that borrower
moral hazard can be controlled by requiring that borrowers
contribute some of their own funds-a
requirement not unlike the capital requirements that banks face.
Finally, Peck and Shell (1999) also
examine policies that might influence the probability of bank
runs, but focus on deposit contracts that
permit the suspension of convertibility and on government
restrictions on banks' portfolios of loans.
5 Further, Wallace (1988) has argued that there is an
inconsistency in the Diamond-Dybvig
model's treatment of deposit insurance. The spatial separation
that motivates banking appears
inconsistent with the ability of governments to provide deposit
insurance. However, Wallace goes on
to point out that "...this argument does not say that any kind of
deposit insurance is infeasible. It only
says that the policy that Diamond and Dybvig identify with
deposit insurance is infeasible..." (p. 13).
We are in complete agreement; clearly the financing of deposit
insurance must be credible to
eliminate certain equilibria. Therefore, in contrast to Diamond
and Dybvig, we rely on the presence
of an outside group of agents ("taxpayers") as a tax base.
Essentially, the government has enough
information to tax labor income without needing to overcome
any spatial separation constraints.
56
This content downloaded from 141.161.91.14 on Sat, 30 Mar
2019 02:57:00 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
DEPOSIT INSURANCE AND INCENTIVES
model does not incorporate the moral hazard considerations
seen to be central to
recent policy debates. Deposit insurance avoids bank runs but
has adverse incentive
effects: it implies less monitoring by depositors, which allows
banks to hold riskier
portfolios. In fact, if deposit insurance is complete enough,
depositors' and banks'
interests are aligned: both types of agents are eager to hold
high-risk portfolios,
effectively gambling with taxpayers' money. Thus a trade-off
emerges between
providing insurance against bank runs and monitoring
incentives.
By characterizing this trade-off, our model permits a derivation
of the optimal
degree of deposit insurance. In general, deposit insurance with
depositor monitoring
is not sufficient to support the first-best outcome. However,
appropriately designed
capital requirements can eliminate the incentive problem
caused by deposit insur-
ance and support the first-best allocation.
From the perspective of our model, the experience in the U.S.
during the 1980s
suggests two forms of regulatory failure. First, capital
requirements were inadequate.
Second, the relaxation of Regulation Q allowed banks to more
aggressively compete
for deposits, which, along with deposit insurance, led to
excessively risky investment.
This is certainly not a novel story but one that appears here in a
consistent, formal
framework.
2. MODEL
The model is a modified version of Diamond-Dybvig (1983).
There are N,
ex ante identical, agents in the economy who are each born
with a unit endow-
ment, which they deposit with an intermediary in period 0.6 At
the start of period
1, agents are informed about their taste types. A fraction r learn
that they obtain
utility from period 1 consumption only (early consumers),
while the others obtain
utility exclusively from period 2 consumption (late consumers).
As in the first part
of Diamond and Dybvig (1983), assume that n is nonstochastic
and known to all
agents.7 Denote by CE and CL the consumption levels for early
and late con-
sumers, respectively, and let U(c) represent their utility
function over consump-
tion. Assume that U(') is strictly increasing and strictly
concave, U'(0)= oo, and
U(0) =0.
There are two technologies available for transferring resources
over time. First,
there is a productive technology that is not completely liquid.
This technology
provides a means of shifting resources from period 0 to 2, with
a return of R > 1 over
the two periods. However, liquidation of projects using this
technique yields only one
unit in period 1 per unit of period 0 investment. Second, there
is a storage tech-
nology, available to both intermediaries and consumers, that
yields one unit in
6 In Cooper and Ross (1998) we allow consumers to make their
own investments rather than using
an intermediary and prove that using an intermediary in this
structure always weakly dominates
autarky.
7 In the last part of their article they consider the importance
of aggregate uncertainty to argue
further in favor of deposit insurance instead of policies that
suspend convertibility.
57
This content downloaded from 141.161.91.14 on Sat, 30 Mar
2019 02:57:00 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
COOPER AND ROSS
period t + 1 per unit of period t investment, t = 0, 1. While not
as productive as the
illiquid technology over two periods, storage provides the same
one-period return.8
The intermediary operates in a competitive environment, which
compels it to offer
contracts that maximize consumers' ex ante expected utility
subject to a break-even
constraint. If the ex post consumer taste types were costlessly
verifiable it would
therefore offer a contract 6* = (c, cL) solving
(1) max 7rU(cE) + (1 - 7)U(cL)
CE,CL
(1 - 7)cL s.t. 1 = CE +1
From the first-order conditions, the optimal contract satisfies
(2) U'(c) = RU'(cL)
Since R > 1, the strict concavity of U(.) implies that cE < c4
for (2) to hold.
Diamond and Dybvig establish that when consumer tastes are
private information,
multiple equilibria may exist. The contracting problem can be
formulated with three
stages. First, the contract is set by the intermediary, which
specifies a consumption
level for each type of consumer independent of the number of
consumers claiming to
be each type.9 Second, agents learn their preferences and these
are announced to the
intermediary. Finally, the allocation of goods to agents is
determined by the contract.
The first-best outcome with the contract b* will be one
equilibrium of this game.
Truth telling is a dominant strategy for early consumers while
truth telling by late
consumers is a best response to truth telling by all other late
consumers.
Under b* there may also exist an equilibrium in which all late
consumers mis-
represent their tastes and announce that they are early
consumers. This can be an
equilibrium if the intermediary does not have sufficient
resources (including liqui-
dated illiquid investments) to provide cE to all agents. As in
the Diamond-Dybvig
model, the late consumers who do not withdraw in period 1
obtain a pro rata share of
the bank's period 2 assets. This equilibrium with
misrepresentation is termed a
"bank run."
The first-best allocation is vulnerable to runs iff cE > 1:
otherwise, the interme-
diary would have sufficient resources to meet the demand of cE
by all agents in
period 1. Diamond and Dybvig (1983) show that if agents are
sufficiently risk averse,
then cE will exceed 1.
8 In this setup, which comes from Diamond and Dybvig,
returns on investments made in this
productive technology are always (weakly) greater than those
in the alternative (storage). In Cooper
and Ross (1998) we extend the model by adding a liquidation
cost to these illiquid projects that
renders the one-period return to liquidated investments less
than the alternative. This expands the
set of conditions under which bank runs can occur and
influences agents' investment and contract
choices. It does not, however, have implications for the results
described below so we have chosen to
work with the simpler model here.
9 Thus, in particular, it is not feasible for the bank to
accumulate information about withdrawals
and make payments to depositors contingent on this
information. Further, agents are unable to meet
at a common location after period 0, thus eliminating the types
of ex post markets considered in, for
example, Jacklin (1987).
58
This content downloaded from 141.161.91.14 on Sat, 30 Mar
2019 02:57:00 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
DEPOSIT INSURANCE AND INCENTIVES
As described in Alonso (1996) and Cooper and Ross (1991,
1998), there are
essentially two ways the intermediary can optimally respond to
the possibility of
multiple equilibria. One is to find the best contract available
that is not vulnerable to
runs. This best runs-preventing contract comes from solving (1)
with the added
constraint CE < 1 so that there are always sufficient resources
available in period 1 to
pay all consumers. Concavity arguments demonstrate that if the
first-best contract is
vulnerable to runs (i.e., c3 > 1), the best runs-preventing
contract will involve CE= 1
and CL = R.
As an alternative, one might construct a model of the
equilibrium selection pro-
cess and solve for the optimal contract. One simple model
relies on the existence of
publicly observable, but not contractible, variables (sunspots)
that correlate agents'
behavior at a particular equilibrium of the game.10 Instead of
preventing runs,
the intermediary adjusts the contract to reduce the impact of
runs in the event they
arise.
Suppose that with probability q there is a wave of economy-
wide pessimism that
determines the beliefs of depositors. If the outstanding contract
has a runs equilib-
rium the pessimism leads to a bank run. With probability (1 -
q), there is optimism
and no run occurs. In this way, the beliefs of depositors are
tied to a move of nature
that determines their actions. The intermediary recognizes this
dependence in de-
signing the optimal contract.
Taking the probability of liquidation, q, as given, the contract
solves (assuming
CE> 1)
(3) max(1 - q)[nU(cE) + (1 - m)U(CL)] + qU(cE)(1/cE)
CE,CL
(1 - t)cL
s.t. 1 = 7cE + -
Let 6(q) be the contract solving this problem.1 Cooper and
Ross (1998) show the
existence of a critical q* C (0, 1) such that the best runs-
preventing contract domi-
nates the best contract with runs if q > q* and the reverse holds
if q < q*.
3. SUPPORTING THE FIRST-BEST: DEPOSIT INSURANCE
AND CAPITAL REQUIREMENTS
The previous section characterizes the optimal response of a
private bank facing
the prospect of a run. Regardless of whether the intermediary
optimally adopts a
runs-preventing contract or allows runs, the possibility of bank
runs clearly lowers
expected utility below that attainable in the first-best solution.
This naturally raises
10 Bental et al. (1990) and Freeman (1988) also adopt a
sunspots approach. In contrast to our
work, those articles allow for sunspot-contingent contracts.
While it is convenient to think of sunspots
as determining which equilibrium of the subgame will be
observed, contracts contingent on these
events are assumed to be infeasible.
1 Here an agent receives CE with probability liCE in the event
of a run, which occurs with
probability q. Note that if the solution to (3) involved CE < 1 it
would in fact be runs-preventing and
therefore be dominated by the best runs-preventing contract
(CE = 1 and CL = R).
59
This content downloaded from 141.161.91.14 on Sat, 30 Mar
2019 02:57:00 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
COOPER AND ROSS
the question of whether some government intervention in the
form of deposit in-
surance or other instrument could prevent runs and thus
improve welfare.12
Deposit insurance is a contract set by the government that
provides a payment to
depositors in the event that the bank is unable to meet its
obligations.13 Diamond
and Dybvig argue that a simple deposit insurance scheme will
eliminate bank runs in
their model. However, their argument leaves aside the adverse
incentive effects of
deposit insurance on both the investment strategy of the
intermediary and the
monitoring decisions of depositors. We study this by adding
both moral hazard and
monitoring by depositors to our model. Our main result in this
section is that an
appropriately designed capital requirement coupled with
deposit insurance can avoid
bank runs without creating severe moral hazard problems.
3.1. Extended Model. We modify the basic model in a number
of ways, detailed
in the subsections that follow. First, we introduce a richer
investment choice for the
banks. Second, we allow for a monitoring decision by
depositors. Third, we introduce
both deposit insurance and capital requirements as policy
instruments for the gov-
ernment.
The sequence of events in period 0 is as follows: First, the
government sets a
deposit insurance policy. In general, the government contract
stipulates payments to
early and late consumers as a function of the deposit contract
in the event the
intermediary is unable to make its promised payments. We
denote the payments to
early and late consumers as I(CE) and I(CL) respectively. Since
the government is
unable to observe the types of private agents, it too must rely
on the agents' an-
nouncements. Put differently, those agents who appear at the
intermediary in period
1 are termed early consumers and are eligible for the
government insurance over CE
in the event the intermediary is unable to meet its obligations.
Likewise, an agent
who makes the announcement of being a late consumer is
eligible for government
insurance over CL if the bank fails in period 2. Importantly, if
a bank fails in period 1,
then late consumers will not receive insurance over CL.
Instead, they will receive the
same payment as early consumers if a bank fails in period 1.
Note that we assume
that government insurance policy depends on the deposit
contract offered by the
intermediary.
Second, the competitive banks offer a contract, 6. Depositors
then decide on
the allocation of their endowment and whether to monitor the
bank. If the bank
12 For the purposes of this exercise, we do not consider private
deposit insurance schemes.
13 For simplicity, assume that the tax obligations to finance
deposit insurance fall upon agents who
are not depositors. Hence we do not consider the possibility
that intermediaries make payments into
a deposit insurance pool but rather focus on the obligations of
taxpayers to the system. Here we
imagine a government policy that provides deposit insurance to
agents who arrive at the bank after
the bank has exhausted resources and then taxes, say, the
endowment of a group of agents in the
economy not involved with the intermediary or even the
endowment of the next generation of
depositors, as in Freeman (1988), to finance these transfers. We
assume that the social welfare
function is such that providing this insurance is desirable. The
key point is that there must be a
government taxation scheme that is not inconsistent with
isolation that is capable of generating the
needed revenues.
60
This content downloaded from 141.161.91.14 on Sat, 30 Mar
2019 02:57:00 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
DEPOSIT INSURANCE AND INCENTIVES
is monitored, investment decisions are observable to all agents.
The depositors
then learn their taste types. Finally, the bank manager allocates
the funds to the
two investments. Our choice of timing here is not very
restrictive: the outcome of
this model and that with simultaneous moves by the monitor(s)
and the banker
are the same though it is important that the monitoring occurs
before the types
are realized.
3.1.1. Richer technology. To allow the bank an avenue for
moral hazard, as-
sume that there exists a second, multiperiod technology that
yields a second period
return of 2R with probability v and 0 otherwise. Further,
assume that 2 > 1 and
v2 < 1 so that this risky technique has a higher return if it is
successful but a lower
expected return than the riskless illiquid investment. Thus, the
riskless two-period
investment is preferred to the risky illiquid investment by all
risk averters.14 As with
the riskless illiquid technology, this alternative technology also
yields one unit in
period 1 per unit invested in period 0.
The bank's investment policy is chosen by a risk-neutral
manager who represents
the bank's owners (shareholders). We assume that any funds
remaining after the
payment of cL to the late consumers are retained by the
shareholders of the bank. As
before, if the intermediary does not have sufficient funds for
the late consumers,
then these agents (and not the shareholders) have rights to a
pro rata share of the
bank's resources.
As we shall see, under some contracts, the manager may have
an incentive to
invest using the risky technology. In particular, in the absence
of a minimum capital
requirement, the risky investment is preferred by the manager
since 2 > 1 gives him
(i.e., the shareholders) a chance at a high return.15 When
deposit insurance is suf-
ficiently generous, depositors will not care that the bank
undertakes risky invest-
ments.
More formally, suppose that the bank offered depositors the
first-best contract 6*
and that the government provides depositors with complete
deposit insurance; i.e.,
I(cL)= CL. Let i denote the amount of resources (per unit of
deposit) that the in-
termediary places in the risky illiquid investment. Then i is
chosen to
max[v(i2R + (1 - i - nrc)R - (1 - n)c) + (1 - v)max((1 - i- rc* )R
- (1 - n)cj, 0)]
The max operator appears here since the bank may not have
enough resources to
meet the needs of depositors when the risky investment fails.
Since the inter-
mediary earns zero profits in the first-best contract when it
invests all of its funds
in the riskless illiquid technology, for any i > 0, the
intermediary has zero return
in the state in which the risky investment fails. Further, with
vA < 1, the inter-
mediary's expected return is positive and increasing in i. Thus
the solution is
for the intermediary to place all funds in the risky illiquid
investment. Since
14 That is, vU(RX) + (1 - v)U(O) < U(vRA) < U(R) for any
concave U(.).
15 "For example, if a bank's liabilities are deposits insured
with fixed-rate Federal Deposit
Insurance Corporation (FDIC) insurance, it is well known that
the bank may have an incentive to
select very risky assets since the deposit insurers bear the brunt
of downside risk but the bank owners
get the benefit of the upside risk" (Diamond and Dybvig, 1986,
p. 59).
61
This content downloaded from 141.161.91.14 on Sat, 30 Mar
2019 02:57:00 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
COOPER AND ROSS
depositors receive full deposit insurance, they have no
incentive to oppose this
investment strategy.
3.1.2. Depositor monitoring. The second change to our model is
the inclusion of
a monitoring decision on the part of depositors. Any depositor
who monitors incurs a
cost r (modeled as a utility loss) and can force the bank to
adopt the depositor's
desired portfolio.16 Given the moral hazard problem outlined
above, depositor
monitoring is a potentially important element in overcoming
the incentive of banks
to invest in risky ventures.
We begin the analysis by studying the monitoring decisions by
the depositors given
the investment choices by the manager, the level of deposit
insurance provided by
the government, and a deposit contract, (CE, CL). We consider
here the case of a
single depositor, but the qualitative results can be extended to
the multidepositor
case.17 If the bank has an incentive to invest in the risky
technique, then monitoring
will occur iff
(4) (1 - 7r)(1 - v)(1 - q)[U(cL)- U(I(cL))] > r
The left-hand side is the expected gain to the depositor from
turning the problem
into one of full information for a given value of CL and the
right-hand side is the
monitoring cost. Note that this condition incorporates the
assertion that if moni-
toring did not occur, the bank would invest in the risky
technology that would yield
the depositor CL with probability v. Further, as the monitoring
decision is made in
period 0, the individual values the information only if he is a
late consumer, which
happens with probability (1 - n). Finally, the gains to
monitoring are lost if there is a
bank run since both the risky and riskless illiquid techniques
generate equal returns
over the first period. So, the left-hand side of (4) includes (1 -
q), the probability of
optimism.
The influence of deposit insurance on monitoring is apparent
from this condition.
If I(CL) is close to CL for all levels of late consumption, then
the single agent has no
incentive to monitor. However, for small levels of insurance,
monitoring will take
place. For this analysis, we assume that when there is no
deposit insurance, a single
depositor will monitor if CL = CL.
16 Calomiris and Kahn (1991) model monitoring as a private
activity though the outcome of
monitoring is made public. The incentives to monitor are
created by sequential service in which the
agents who monitor are "first in line." Our results are robust to
assuming that the information
generated by monitoring is private.
17 The existence of multiple depositors creates a number of
interesting complications due to
free riding on the monitoring of others. One possibility of
resolving this is via a cooperative
agreement on monitoring: an accounting firm is retained as part
of the deposit arrangement.
Alternatively, in the noncooperative game between depositors
to determine the level of
monitoring by each, there will be asymmetric equilibria in
which one depositor monitors and the
others free ride. There may also be equilibria in which
monitoring costs are shared by a subset of
the depositors. Finally, there may also be a mixed-strategy
equilibrium that each agent monitors
with some probability. Such a model is considered in an
expanded version of this article available
from the authors.
62
This content downloaded from 141.161.91.14 on Sat, 30 Mar
2019 02:57:00 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
DEPOSIT INSURANCE AND INCENTIVES
3.2. Capital Requirements. Consider a second instrument of
government policy:
a requirement on the ratio of debt to equity financing for an
intermediary. To be
precise, suppose that the shareholders of the intermediary are
required by the
government to contribute K units of the numeraire good per
unit of deposit to the
intermediary's capital account.
Let i again denote the funds (per unit of deposit) that the
intermediary places in
the risky investment. Then the portfolio choice of the
intermediary is determined
from
(5) max[v(i2R + ((K + 1) - i - 7cE)R - (1 - 7)CL)
+ (1 - v) max((1 + K - i - 7CE)R - (1 - 7t)CL, 0)]
The first part of this expression applies to the case of a
successful risky invest-
ment outcome, in which case the shareholders of the bank earn
a high return of
AR on the i units placed into the risky illiquid investment.
With probability
(1 - v), however, the risky investment fails and the bank's
resources are limited to
(1 + K -i- - i CE), which earns a return of R. These funds are
then used to
meet the demands of late consumers, given by (1 - 7t)CL. It is
possible that the
intermediary does not have sufficient resources to meet these
demands by late
consumers so that the bank's shareholders obtain 0. Hence the
max operator
in (5).
In fact, the nonlinearity created by the possibility of
bankruptcy is central to the
moral hazard problem faced by a bank. In particular, suppose
that the terms of the
contract offered depositors are such that there exists a level of
risky illiquid in-
vestment (i') satisfying
(1 + K - i' - 7CE)R = (1 - 7)CL
At this critical level of risky investment, the firm has zero
profits in the second
period when the risky project fails. It is easy to see that the
expected payoff of
the intermediary is higher at i = 0 than for any i c (0, i') since
shareholders bear
all of the downside risk from investing more resources in the
risky illiquid project
for i in this interval. For any i > i', shareholders do not bear the
risk of this
investment, so it is profitable to put more funds in the risky
investment. Thus,
from this optimization problem, the choice of the intermediary
is reduced to
placing either all of the funds in the risky investment or all of
the funds in the
riskless investment.
3.3. Supporting the First-Best Allocation. The point of the
following proposi-
tion is that if the capital requirement is sufficiently large,
shareholders will no
longer prefer to gamble with depositors' funds and thus the
moral hazard problem
is solved. Further, with complete deposit insurance, bank runs
are eliminated.
Finally, depositors will have no need to monitor the bank since
they are completely
insured.
63
This content downloaded from 141.161.91.14 on Sat, 30 Mar
2019 02:57:00 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
COOPER AND ROSS
Formally:
PROPOSITION 1. If I(CL) = CL for CL < C, I(CL) = CL for
CL > C, I(CE) = CE for
CE < CE, I(CE) = CE for CE > CE, and K > K* - [v(2 - 1)]/[1 -
2v], then the first-best
allocation of (c , cL) is achievable without bank runs and
without monitoring.
PROOF. Since deposit insurance is complete up to (c4, cL), if
the first-best con-
tract is offered, bank runs will be eliminated.
Using the first-best contract, (5) becomes
(6) max[v(i)R + ((K + 1) - i - rcc)R - (1 - n)c*)
+ (1 - v) max((1 + K - i - rnc)R - (1 - n)c*, 0)]
Using the resource constraint of R = (1 - n)c4 + R7rc, this
reduces to
(7) max[v(i2R + (K - i)R) + (1 - v) max((K - i)R, 0)]
Clearly, i will be set to 0 or to its maximal value of (1 + K)
since any interior choice of
i is dominated by one of these extremes. The profits of the
intermediary are higher at
i=O than at i = 1 + K iff
RK > v(l + K)XR - Rv
which reduces to the condition given in the proposition.
Finally, from the definition of the first-best, there is no other
contract that can
increase the expected utility of the consumer. Thus, if capital
requirements meet the
bound given in the proposition, banks will offer the first-best
contract to depositors
and will not have any incentive to invest in the risky
technology. Depositors will
therefore have no incentive to monitor and, given the presence
of complete deposit
insurance, there will be no bank runs. i
The point of this proposition is that an adequate equity capital
base can provide
sufficient incentive to owners managers to overcome the moral
hazard problems
without the need for monitoring by depositors. In this case,
deposit insurance can
prevent bank runs without creating incentive problems and the
first-best allocation,
given as the solution to (2), can be supported.18
Note that the capital requirement does not specify how the
intermediary must
invest the funds that shareholders provide. In the proof of
Proposition 1, we find that
if the intermediary has an incentive to invest depositors' funds
in the risky illiquid
technology (which occurs iff K < K*), then the intermediary
will invest shareholders'
funds in the risky venture as well. If it did not do so, the
intermediary would be
forced to pay depositors all of the shareholders' funds in the
event that the risky
venture failed. Hence the incentive to gamble with depositors'
funds will spill over to
the allocation of shareholders' funds as well.
18 As a referee has correctly pointed out, the assumption of
risk neutrality on the part of the bank
is important to this result. If the bank manager and
shareholders were risk averse, there would be
additional costs associated with investing own-capital in a bank
with uncertain returns.
64
This content downloaded from 141.161.91.14 on Sat, 30 Mar
2019 02:57:00 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
DEPOSIT INSURANCE AND INCENTIVES
The effects of parameter changes on the critical level of capital
K* are of interest.
For example, a mean-preserving spread on the returns from the
risky asset, as rep-
resented by a combination of increasing i and decreasing v that
leaves 2v constant,
will increase K*. That is, as the probability of the risky asset
succeeding falls, holding
the expected return constant, more capital will be needed to
deter morally hazardous
investment behavior. This is a fairly intuitive result. However,
if we increase either i
or v while holding the other fixed-in either case increasing the
efficiency of the risky
investment-the minimum capital requirement actually rises. As
the risky asset is
more attractive, we need to impose tighter minimum capital
requirements.
4. THE SAVINGS AND LOAN CRISIS
The model developed here is also useful in understanding the
role that sub-
optimal regulatory policies played in the S&L crisis in the
United States in the
1980s.19 This crisis, almost certainly one of the most
important events in
American banking history, has imposed costs on taxpayers that
continue to
mount.
In the late 1970s and early 1980s interest rates climbed
substantially, and S&Ls
and some banks were squeezed as depositors withdrew funds to
put them into
higher-yielding Treasury Bills and money market funds while
the long-term
mortgages that provided much of the S&L income were fixed at
interest rates far
below market rates. Regulatory reforms introduced to help
S&Ls compete (e.g.,
flexible rate mortgages), the relaxation of controls on interest
rates paid (Regu-
lation Q), and the expansion of deposit insurance protection
combined with a
lack of regulatory oversight to introduce severe problems of
moral hazard. Thrifts
with low levels of net worth now had the opportunity to gamble
with other
people's (i.e., taxpayers') money and insured depositors had
little incentive to
monitor their thrifts. Indeed, if taxpayers were going to cover
the downside,
depositors shared the thrift owners' interest in risky
investments with high upside
potential, even if the expected yield was low. For a time, this
strategy led to rapid
growth of S&Ls, but eventually the poor quality of their
investments brought
many down.
To see how our model can explain important aspects of the
S&L crisis, we focus on
two key aspects of White's (1991) description of the S&L
crisis: (i) the removal of
Regulation Q and (ii) the inadequacy of capital requirements.
Removing Regulation
Q allowed banks more flexibility in competing for depositors,
that is, greater latitude
in setting CE and CL. One view of Regulation Q was that it
essentially mandated runs-
preventing contracts, and its repeal allowed banks to offer
contracts that were vul-
nerable to runs. When squeezed by the new pressure to offer
higher interest rates to
attract deposits even while many of their loans (often
mortgages) were set at very low
rates, many smaller institutions became seriously
undercapitalized-a deficiency not
19 For background on the crisis and its causes, see, for
example, White (1991), Grossman (1992),
and Dewatripont and Tirole (1994, Chapter 4).
65
This content downloaded from 141.161.91.14 on Sat, 30 Mar
2019 02:57:00 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
COOPER AND ROSS
always noticed by regulators failing to measure the values of
assets at current market
prices.20
While the inadequate capitalization may have changed the
incentives of banks
to avoid risky projects, the existence of deposit insurance
implied that depositors
were still willing to place funds in these institutions. It is
important to recognize
that, in our model, deposit insurance does not create the moral
hazard problem:
the manager's interest in the risky asset would exist in the
absence of insurance.
What the deposit insurance does is reduce the incentive of
depositors to monitor
banks. In the case of many of the failed S&Ls, the interests of
these agents
became aligned with those of the banks and jointly they
gambled with taxpayers'
money.21
To formalize this point, we consider the implications of
suboptimal deposit in-
surance and inadequate capital requirements. In particular, we
assume that no
capital requirements are in place. This assumption simplifies
the analysis and
captures the theme that a key aspect of this experience was
inadequate capital
requirements. While outside our model, one could imagine that
a period of de-
flation led to a reduction in the value of capital and thus the
inadequacy of existing
capital requirements.22 Further, we consider a relatively
simple deposit insurance
scheme, in which the government provides a fraction c of the
resources owed to
depositors (both early and/or late types) when a bank fails.23
In particular, recall
that we assume that if a bank fails in period 1, both early and
late consumers
receive a fraction of CE. Essentially, the government insures
current deposits rather
than promised payments.
While admittedly quite crude, this configuration of policy
choices and market
conditions matches the description of the savings and loan
industry in the 1980s
provided by White (1991). Consider first the extent of deposit
insurance coverage
in the United States. Note that partial insurance is ostensibly a
component of
U.S. policy through limits on coverage. However, it is well
understood that in a
large number of cases, such as Continental Illinois in 1984, the
U.S. government
did provide deposit insurance to individuals with accounts in
excess of the
20 White (1991) admits that the regulators had a very difficult
job in this new environment and that
they even suffered from some very bad luck. For example, a
key Texas office was moved at just the
wrong time-disrupting the work of regulators just when their
oversight was needed the most.
21 In related research, Grossman (1992) studies the risk-taking
behavior of insured and uninsured
thrift institutions in Milwaukee and Chicago during the 1930s.
He finds evidence of moral hazard in
that after a few years of deposit insurance coverage, thrifts
would move toward holding riskier
portfolios. He also finds that the level of regulatory oversight
influenced the degree of risk taking.
Federally insured thrifts were the most heavily regulated and
took on less risk than their state-
chartered counterparts. And the stricter regulation in Wisconsin
led thrifts in that state to build less
risky portfolios than those of state-chartered thrifts in Illinois,
where the regulations were less
stringent.
22 Mechanisms such as this, where deflation leads to incentive
problems, are often discussed in the
literature on financial frictions.
23 By assumption, the deposit insurance covers the same
fraction of early and late consumption.
Hence, more sophisticated policies that might prevent runs
without creating a moral hazard problem
by insuring early consumption only are not considered.
66
This content downloaded from 141.161.91.14 on Sat, 30 Mar
2019 02:57:00 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
DEPOSIT INSURANCE AND INCENTIVES
$100,000 cap.24 Diamond and Dybvig (1986) suggest that
since the government
did not credibly commit ex ante to pay off all depositors
(which might have
protected the bank from the capital flight it experienced) but
then covered those
losses ex post, "they incurred the expense of deposit insurance
without the
benefits" (p. 64).
With regard to capital requirements, the losses suffered by
many S&Ls had ef-
fectively reduced their capital to levels so low that
shareholders had relatively little
to lose from making high-risk investments. With these
investments, they were es-
sentially gambling with taxpayers' money. Hence it is of
interest to determine the
model's predictions under this scenario, to see if we have a
structure that can explain
what actually happened.
There is an obvious concern associated with this
characterization of deposit in-
surance: taking a as given, an intermediary has the incentive to
make outrageous
promises to depositors, given that the government is insuring
these offers. While the
removal of Regulation Q certainly gave the intermediaries more
latitude, some
constraint on the choice of 6 = (CE, CL) must be imposed. In
our analysis, we assume
that the government will provide insurance iff the terms of 3
solve the contracting
problem given the level of deposit insurance and under the
presumption that the
bank will not invest in the risky illiquid technology. Given that
the environment is
public information, there is no reason for the government to
insure contracts that are
only reasonable if the bank commits moral hazard and invests
in risky projects. As a
consequence, the bank is unable to pass along gains from
excessive risk taking to
depositors.25
To make the role of monitoring clear, we make use of (4) and
assume that there is
effectively only a single agent who can either monitor the bank
or not. Since the cost
of monitoring has been assumed to take the form of a utility
loss, the contracting
problems specified above do not change as we vary the cost of
monitoring.
Further, following Proposition 1, the bank chooses to invest
funds in either the
risky illiquid investment project or the riskless illiquid
investment project.
24 The Federal Deposit Insurance Company employs two
strategies to deal with failed institutions:
deposit payoff and deposit assumption. In the former case,
depositors simply receive their funds and
the bank is closed. In the latter case, the bank is taken over by
another institution and FDIC funds
are used to compensate the acquiring bank. In this case, large
and small depositors are protected.
Since a large fraction of the resolution of bank failures has
been through deposit assumption, large
depositors have, in effect, received insurance. The FDIC
Annual Report provides a more complete
explanation and data on the frequency of use of these policies.
We are grateful to Warren Weber and
Art Rolnick for discussions of this point.
25 One could add an element of unobservable side payments
from the bank to depositors into the
model to allow the sharing of these gains. As discussed below,
this would certainly influence the
characterization of the critical value of deposit insurance in
Proposition 2 but not change the results
qualitatively. An alternative approach that would permit some
of the gains from this risk taking to be
passed on to depositors would allow the bank to offer
depositors contracts that it would have the
resources to fully honor only if the risky investment was
successful. That is, suppose regulators could
not observe v and believed the bank's claim that v = 1. In this
case with full deposit insurance the
bank can-indeed competition will force it to-provide more
generous deposit contracts knowing
that the deposit insurer will certainly be needed if the risky
project fails. So again we have the
depositors and shareholders both wanting to invest in the risky,
inefficient project.
67
This content downloaded from 141.161.91.14 on Sat, 30 Mar
2019 02:57:00 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
COOPER AND ROSS
This discrete choice highlights the moral hazard problem for
the bank and its
depositors.
Finally, we assume that q is sufficiently small so that the
contract with runs
dominates the runs-preventing contract in the absence of
deposit insurance. Hence,
when we characterize the optimal contract in the presence of
deposit insurance, the
assumption that q is small implies that the private sector will
not adopt runs-
preventing contracts. We comment below on the robustness of
our results to the
alternative assumption that q is large enough to warrant the
adoption of runs-
preventing contracts, at least for some levels of deposit
insurance.
With complete deposit insurance (c = 1), the intermediary will
prefer to invest
in the risky illiquid technology and depositors will not care
since, in effect, they
are gambling with other agents' money. At the other extreme of
no deposit
insurance (a = 0), there is no moral hazard problem if
monitoring costs are low
enough so that depositors monitor the intermediary and thus
force the inter-
mediary to invest in the riskless illiquid technique. From this,
it is not surprising
that there exists a critical level of deposit insurance, denoted
a', at which
depositors are indifferent between investment in the risky and
riskless ventures.
This leads to the following characterization of the optimal level
of deposit
insurance, c*.
PROPOSITION 2. The optimal level of deposit insurance will
be at one of two
levels, Ca* E {a', 1}.
PROOF. To understand the possibility of a* = o', consider first
the design of the
best contract allowing for runs in the presence of deposit
insurance assuming that the
intermediary uses the riskless illiquid technique. This is (3)
modified to include
deposit insurance, i.e.,
(8) max(1 - q)[7U(cE) + (1 - T)U(CL)] + q U(CE) ( + U(OCCE)
( 1 CE,CL CE  CE
s.t. (1 - n)cL = R(1 - 71CE)
Let b(c) = (cE(x), cL(a)) denote the solution to this contracting
problem.
Now consider the optimal contract allowing for runs in the
presence of deposit
insurance assuming that the intermediary uses the risky illiquid
technique. This is
clearly preferred by the intermediary, given that its
shareholders benefit when
the risky project succeeds and bear no risk if it fails. Put
differently, with no
capital requirement, the bank will have an incentive to invest in
the risky
technique.
Will the depositors monitor? Given 65(a) and the assumption of
a single monitor,
(4) becomes
(9) (1 - 7)(1 - v)(1 - q)[U(cL(x)) - U(0c(cL(a)))] > r
Let a' be the level of deposit insurance such that (9) holds as an
equality. We
assume that r is small enough so that monitoring will occur at a
= 0 but not for a
near 1. So by continuity of U(.) and hence continuity of the
solution to (8), a' e (0, 1).
In sum, if the government sets the level of deposit insurance at
a', it would anticipate
68
This content downloaded from 141.161.91.14 on Sat, 30 Mar
2019 02:57:00 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
DEPOSIT INSURANCE AND INCENTIVES
that the optimal contract would solve (8) and the depositor
would be indifferent
between monitoring and not monitoring.
At a = 1, there will be no bank runs and no monitoring. Hence,
investment will be
in the risky illiquid investment.
It is straightforward to see that only two values of deposit
insurance are relevant.
For values of a c [0, c'], there is no moral hazard as the bank is
always monitored.
Starting at a 0, increases in a would just change the level of
insurance given to
depositors. As the best contract does not eliminate runs, this
insurance may have
social value. For values of a c (c', 1), there is a moral hazard
problem but there are
no additional incentive problems created by increasing the
level of deposit insur-
ance from o' toward 1. Hence, it is sufficient to compare social
welfare at c' with
that at 1. U
Intuitively, the reduction of the optimal deposit insurance rate
to the two possible
outcomes reflects the trade-off between insurance and moral
hazard. For c < a',
consumers monitor and prevent the risky venture. At a = a', the
incentives change and
for a > c', depositors are unwilling to monitor and thus
intermediaries choose risky
illiquid investments. Thus, a key aspect of the proof concerns
the existence of a'.
Thus, with inadequate capital requirements, the government is
forced to choose
between the insurance gains from deposit insurance and its
adverse incentive effects.
In our model, this trade-off is reflected in the choice between
a* = 1 and a* = c'. By
continuity, if q is sufficiently close to zero so that the prospect
of runs is infinitesimal,
then the best policy is to adopt partial deposit insurance and
thus avoid bank moral
hazard problems. Alternatively, if the moral hazard problem is
itself small, say
because vi is near 1, then it is best to offer full deposit
insurance.
Regardless of whether deposit insurance is full or partial, it is
important to note
that the first-best outcome is not achieved. In the case of
partial deposit insurance,
depositors will monitor the bank but they face either strategic
uncertainty or the
inefficiencies created by a runs-preventing contract. Full
deposit insurance clearly
creates an incentive problem since the interests of the bank and
its depositors are
aligned. Thus, even if monitoring costs are 0, the first-best is
not obtained.
We consider the robustness of these results with respect to two
important assump-
tions. First, if monitoring was the outcome of the interaction of
multiple agents rather
than just one, then the conditions for monitoring would not be
given by (4) and the
optimal action by the government would change. We show
elsewhere that the critical
value of a characterized in Proposition 2 is relevant for the
case of multiple depositors.
In particular, if a > ', then the Nash equilibrium is for no
depositor to monitor. That is,
if no other depositor monitors, then the remaining agent uses
(4) to determine whether
or not monitoring is desirable so that c' is again the critical
level of insurance. For
a < a', the symmetric Nash equilibrium will entail monitoring
and the probability that
any individual agent monitors will increase as a falls.26
Second, suppose that q was large enough so that, in the absence
of deposit
insurance, banks would have elected to offer runs-preventing
contracts. In such a
26 These results are contained in an earlier version of this
article, available from the authors upon
request.
69
This content downloaded from 141.161.91.14 on Sat, 30 Mar
2019 02:57:00 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
COOPER AND ROSS
case, the provision of partial deposit insurance can have the
perverse effect of
increasing the probability of runs. The insurance can make it
optimal to abandon
the runs-preventing contract and if the insurance is not
complete runs can still
happen. Thus, while with zero monitoring costs the best runs-
preventing contract
will involve neither runs nor moral hazard, adding partial
deposit insurance can
lead to both.
5. CONCLUSIONS
The goal of this article has been to extend the Diamond-Dybvig
framework to
understand the implications of runs and moral hazard for the
evaluation of the costs
and benefits of deposit insurance. In our analysis, as in that of
Diamond-Dybvig,
there is a clear benefit to the provision of deposit insurance as
it prevents runs. The
costs modeled here are associated with a reduction in the
incentives for depositors to
monitor, giving rise to riskier investments by intermediaries.
From the perspective of our model, the first-best allocation is
achievable with a
combination of policies. Deposit insurance is needed to avoid
bank runs. Capital
requirements are needed to overcome the adverse incentive
problems associated
with the provision of deposit insurance.
The article has demonstrated that one potential consequence of
the combination
of an inadequate capital requirement, say due to regulatory
failure, with a generous
deposit insurance fund is the type of banking instability
observed in the U.S. during
the 1980s. We therefore believe that our article contributes to
an understanding of
what happened to many of the failed S&Ls.
This work leaves a number of interesting avenues for future
research. For ex-
ample, we do not explicitly consider here the implications of
risk-based deposit
insurance plans. The 1991 FDIC Improvement Act mandated a
move toward risk-
based premia in the United States and a similar program
appears to be coming to
deposit insurance in Canada. While it might appear that such
policies would solve
the runs problem without introducing moral hazard, much
depends on the timing of
moves. If bank owners can adjust their portfolios after premia
have been paid, then
the problems we analyze here may remain. The premia, once
paid, become a sunk
cost that will not influence future investment behavior. Of
course, in a multiperiod
environment, "punishments" can be administered in the future
in the form of higher
premia, but in the case of banks with depleted capital bases,
and therefore nothing
much to lose, the punishment might come too late.27
While the model developed here does present simple conditions
to achieve
the first-best outcome, potential limitations of this solution
arise from the presence
of moral hazard between bank owners and managers and
difficulties in raising
27 This point is also made by Freixas and Rochet (1997, p.
270). Chan et al. (1992) demonstrate
the impossibility of fairly priced deposit insurance in a model
with asymmetric information and
incentive compatibility constraints. Dewatripont and Tirole
(1994) argue that "it is extremely
difficult to devise proper risk-based premiums, especially if
those are to be determined in a
transparent, nondiscretionary manner" (pp. 60-61). They
characterize the American approach with
premiums ranging from 23 to 31 cents per $100 of deposits as
"very timid."
70
This content downloaded from 141.161.91.14 on Sat, 30 Mar
2019 02:57:00 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
DEPOSIT INSURANCE AND INCENTIVES
sufficient equity capital. Further, the equity capital requirement
must be adjusted
in response to changes in the economic environment. These
adjustments and the
continued monitoring of compliance with this requirement
might be costly. We
leave the question of the second-best policies in this
environment for future
research.
REFERENCES
ALONSO, I., "On Avoiding Bank Runs," Journal of Monetary
Economics 37 (1996), 73-87.
BENTAL, B., Z. ECKSTEIN, AND D. PELED, "Competitive
Banking with Fractional Reserves and
Regulations," working paper no. 10-90, Foerder Institute for
Economic Research, Tel Aviv
University, April 1990.
BESANKO, D., AND G. KANATAS, "Credit Market
Equilibrium with Bank Monitoring and Moral
Hazard," Review of Financial Studies 6 (1993), 213-32.
CALOMIRIS, C., AND C. KAHN, "The Role of Demandable
Debt in Structuring Optimal Banking
Arrangements," American Economic Review 81 (1991), 497-
513.
CHAN, Y., S. GREENBAUM, AND A. THAKOR, "Is Fairly
Priced Deposit Insurance Possible?,"
Journal of Finance 47 (1992), 227-45.
COOPER, R., AND T. W. Ross, "Bank Runs: Liquidity and
Incentives," NBER Working Paper
#3921, November 1991.
AND , "Bank Runs: Liquidity Costs and Investment
Distortions," Journal of Monetary
Economics 41 (1998), 27-38.
DEWATRIPONT, M., AND J. TIROLE, The Prudential
Regulation of Banks (Cambridge, MA: MIT
Press, 1994).
DIAMOND, D., AND P. DYBVIG, "Bank Runs, Deposit
Insurance and Liquidity," Journal of Political
Economy 91 (1983), 401-19.
AND , "Banking Theory, Deposit Insurance and Bank
Regulation," Journal of
Business 59 (1986), 55-68.
FELDSTEIN, M., "The Risks of Economic Crisis:
Introduction," in M. Feldstein, ed., The Risks of
Economic Crisis (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1991).
FREEMAN, S., "Banking as the Provision of Liquidity,"
Journal of Business 61 (1988), 45-64.
FREIXAS, X., AND J.-C. ROCHET, Microeconomics of
Banking (Cambridge, MA: MIT Press, 1997).
GIAMMARINO, R., T. LEWIS, AND D. SAPPINGTON, "An
Incentive Approach to Banking Regu-
lation," Journal of Finance 48 (1993), 1523-42.
GROSSMAN, R. S., "Deposit Insurance, Regulation, and Moral
Hazard in the Thrift Industry: Evi-
dence from the 1930s," American Economic Review 82 (1992),
800-21.
HOLMSTROM, B., AND J. TIROLE, "Financial
Intermediation, Loanable Funds and the Real Sec-
tor," mimeo, IDEI, Toulouse University, 1993.
JACKLIN, C., "Demand Deposits, Trading Restrictions and
Risk Sharing," in E. Prescott and
N. Wallace, eds., Contractual Arrangements for Intertemporal
Trade, Minnesota Studies
in Macroeconomics, Vol. I (Minneapolis: University of
Minnesota Press, 1987).
KORMENDI, R., V. BERNARD, S. C. PIRRONG, AND E.
SNYDER, Crisis Resolution in the Thrift
Industry (Boston: Kluwer Academic Publishers, 1989).
KUPIEC, P., AND J. O'BRIEN, "Deposit Insurance, Bank
Incentives, and the Design of
Regulatory Policy," mimeo, Board of Governors of the Federal
Reserve System, December
1997.
MATUTES, C., AND X. VIVES, "Competition for Deposits,
Fragility and Insurance," Journal of
Financial Intermediation 5 (1996), 184-216.
PECK, J., AND K. SHELL, "Bank Portfolio Restrictions and
Equilibrium Bank Runs," mimeo, Ohio
State University, 1999.
SMITH, B., AND R. WHITE, "The Deposit Insurance System
in Canada: Problems and Proposals for
Change," Canadian Public Policy 14 (1988), 331-46.
71
This content downloaded from 141.161.91.14 on Sat, 30 Mar
2019 02:57:00 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
72 COOPER AND ROSS
WALLACE, N., "Another Attempt to Explain an Illiquid
Banking System: The Diamond-Dybvig
Model with Sequential Service Taken Seriously," Federal
Reserve Bank of Minneapolis
Quarterly Review 12 (1988), 3-16.
WHITE, L., The S&L Debacle: Public Policy Lessons for Bank
and Thrift Regulation (New York:
Oxford University Press, 1991).
This content downloaded from 141.161.91.14 on Sat, 30 Mar
2019 02:57:00 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
Project can be of any length you like, from a few pages to 20
(although I doubt any of you will have 20 pages to write). I do
NOT want you to write random stuff just to fill the pages, I
want to read essential information.
The logic to follow is similar to what you see when you read the
papers we have studied: abstract (very short), introduction
(where you say what your question is and why it is interesting,
and how you will study it) and then the body of the paper.
Finally a conclusion that can be again very short and usually it
is just saying the same things as the abstract.
If you do not have a mathematical model that’s also ok,
although I would encourage you to think through the
frameworks we have seen carefully and you might find useful
material.

More Related Content

Similar to Financial Regulation Lecture 9Based on notes by Marlena El.docx

Chapter 3. Arbitrage (asset) pricing theoryNeil Wallace.docx
Chapter 3. Arbitrage (asset) pricing theoryNeil Wallace.docxChapter 3. Arbitrage (asset) pricing theoryNeil Wallace.docx
Chapter 3. Arbitrage (asset) pricing theoryNeil Wallace.docx
christinemaritza
 
Retirement Portfolio Financial Analysis - Graduate Project
Retirement Portfolio Financial Analysis - Graduate ProjectRetirement Portfolio Financial Analysis - Graduate Project
Retirement Portfolio Financial Analysis - Graduate Project
Medicishi Taylor
 
1st Québec-Ontario Workshop on Insurance Mathematics
1st Québec-Ontario Workshop on Insurance Mathematics1st Québec-Ontario Workshop on Insurance Mathematics
1st Québec-Ontario Workshop on Insurance Mathematics
Arthur Charpentier
 
Chap 18 risk management & capital budgeting
Chap 18   risk management & capital budgetingChap 18   risk management & capital budgeting
Chap 18 risk management & capital budgeting
Arindam Khan
 

Similar to Financial Regulation Lecture 9Based on notes by Marlena El.docx (20)

Presentation socg
Presentation socgPresentation socg
Presentation socg
 
A few solvers for portfolio selection
A few solvers for portfolio selectionA few solvers for portfolio selection
A few solvers for portfolio selection
 
Introduction to lifecontingencies R package
Introduction to lifecontingencies R packageIntroduction to lifecontingencies R package
Introduction to lifecontingencies R package
 
Decision theory
Decision theoryDecision theory
Decision theory
 
Moral Hazard Summary Microeconomics 2016
Moral Hazard Summary Microeconomics 2016Moral Hazard Summary Microeconomics 2016
Moral Hazard Summary Microeconomics 2016
 
Microeconomic Theory Homework Help
Microeconomic Theory Homework HelpMicroeconomic Theory Homework Help
Microeconomic Theory Homework Help
 
Chapter 3. Arbitrage (asset) pricing theoryNeil Wallace.docx
Chapter 3. Arbitrage (asset) pricing theoryNeil Wallace.docxChapter 3. Arbitrage (asset) pricing theoryNeil Wallace.docx
Chapter 3. Arbitrage (asset) pricing theoryNeil Wallace.docx
 
Criticism on Li's Copula Approach
Criticism on Li's Copula ApproachCriticism on Li's Copula Approach
Criticism on Li's Copula Approach
 
Retirement Portfolio Financial Analysis - Graduate Project
Retirement Portfolio Financial Analysis - Graduate ProjectRetirement Portfolio Financial Analysis - Graduate Project
Retirement Portfolio Financial Analysis - Graduate Project
 
Robust Optimal Reinsurance and Investment Problem with p-Thinning Dependent a...
Robust Optimal Reinsurance and Investment Problem with p-Thinning Dependent a...Robust Optimal Reinsurance and Investment Problem with p-Thinning Dependent a...
Robust Optimal Reinsurance and Investment Problem with p-Thinning Dependent a...
 
1st Québec-Ontario Workshop on Insurance Mathematics
1st Québec-Ontario Workshop on Insurance Mathematics1st Québec-Ontario Workshop on Insurance Mathematics
1st Québec-Ontario Workshop on Insurance Mathematics
 
Chap 18 risk management & capital budgeting
Chap 18   risk management & capital budgetingChap 18   risk management & capital budgeting
Chap 18 risk management & capital budgeting
 
Slides ensae-2016-9
Slides ensae-2016-9Slides ensae-2016-9
Slides ensae-2016-9
 
Duration and Convexity
Duration and ConvexityDuration and Convexity
Duration and Convexity
 
Slides ensae 9
Slides ensae 9Slides ensae 9
Slides ensae 9
 
IRJET- Optimization of 1-Bit ALU using Ternary Logic
IRJET- Optimization of 1-Bit ALU using Ternary LogicIRJET- Optimization of 1-Bit ALU using Ternary Logic
IRJET- Optimization of 1-Bit ALU using Ternary Logic
 
Estimating Financial Frictions under Learning
Estimating Financial Frictions under LearningEstimating Financial Frictions under Learning
Estimating Financial Frictions under Learning
 
Modeling of crisis periods in stock markets
Modeling of crisis periods in stock marketsModeling of crisis periods in stock markets
Modeling of crisis periods in stock markets
 
Froyen21
Froyen21Froyen21
Froyen21
 
The Equity Premium Puzzle undera General Utility Function
The Equity Premium Puzzle undera General Utility FunctionThe Equity Premium Puzzle undera General Utility Function
The Equity Premium Puzzle undera General Utility Function
 

More from ericn8

Find a recently (post-2010) published study in your field which .docx
Find a recently (post-2010) published study in your field which .docxFind a recently (post-2010) published study in your field which .docx
Find a recently (post-2010) published study in your field which .docx
ericn8
 

More from ericn8 (20)

Find a recently (post-2010) published study in your field which .docx
Find a recently (post-2010) published study in your field which .docxFind a recently (post-2010) published study in your field which .docx
Find a recently (post-2010) published study in your field which .docx
 
Find a NEWS article that addresses a current political issue o.docx
Find a NEWS article that addresses a current political issue o.docxFind a NEWS article that addresses a current political issue o.docx
Find a NEWS article that addresses a current political issue o.docx
 
Find a recent article on a practice, activity or aspect of the .docx
Find a recent article on a practice, activity or aspect of the .docxFind a recent article on a practice, activity or aspect of the .docx
Find a recent article on a practice, activity or aspect of the .docx
 
Find a program (provide a link to the program) which was developed t.docx
Find a program (provide a link to the program) which was developed t.docxFind a program (provide a link to the program) which was developed t.docx
Find a program (provide a link to the program) which was developed t.docx
 
Find a publicly available secondary dataset that will allow yo.docx
Find a publicly available secondary dataset that will allow yo.docxFind a publicly available secondary dataset that will allow yo.docx
Find a publicly available secondary dataset that will allow yo.docx
 
Find a non-bankruptcy fraud case. Write an academic paper of 3 pages.docx
Find a non-bankruptcy fraud case. Write an academic paper of 3 pages.docxFind a non-bankruptcy fraud case. Write an academic paper of 3 pages.docx
Find a non-bankruptcy fraud case. Write an academic paper of 3 pages.docx
 
Find a newspaper or magazine article that highlights when the politi.docx
Find a newspaper or magazine article that highlights when the politi.docxFind a newspaper or magazine article that highlights when the politi.docx
Find a newspaper or magazine article that highlights when the politi.docx
 
Find a NEWS article that addresses an issue in immigration. (A.docx
Find a NEWS article that addresses an issue in immigration. (A.docxFind a NEWS article that addresses an issue in immigration. (A.docx
Find a NEWS article that addresses an issue in immigration. (A.docx
 
Find a NEWS article that addresses a current economic issue fa.docx
Find a NEWS article that addresses a current economic issue fa.docxFind a NEWS article that addresses a current economic issue fa.docx
Find a NEWS article that addresses a current economic issue fa.docx
 
Find a NEWS article that addresses a recent example of social .docx
Find a NEWS article that addresses a recent example of social .docxFind a NEWS article that addresses a recent example of social .docx
Find a NEWS article that addresses a recent example of social .docx
 
Find a NEWS article that addresses a recent technological deve.docx
Find a NEWS article that addresses a recent technological deve.docxFind a NEWS article that addresses a recent technological deve.docx
Find a NEWS article that addresses a recent technological deve.docx
 
Find a media message (print, commercial, tweet, post, etc.) that is .docx
Find a media message (print, commercial, tweet, post, etc.) that is .docxFind a media message (print, commercial, tweet, post, etc.) that is .docx
Find a media message (print, commercial, tweet, post, etc.) that is .docx
 
Find a current event, within the last year, that involved a crisis o.docx
Find a current event, within the last year, that involved a crisis o.docxFind a current event, within the last year, that involved a crisis o.docx
Find a current event, within the last year, that involved a crisis o.docx
 
FIND a current article ( It should be in-2019) In The News rega.docx
FIND a current article ( It should be in-2019) In The News rega.docxFIND a current article ( It should be in-2019) In The News rega.docx
FIND a current article ( It should be in-2019) In The News rega.docx
 
Find a case that has been investigated by The Innocence Project. Fin.docx
Find a case that has been investigated by The Innocence Project. Fin.docxFind a case that has been investigated by The Innocence Project. Fin.docx
Find a case that has been investigated by The Innocence Project. Fin.docx
 
Find a case study on data mining. Identify the following informa.docx
Find a case study on data mining. Identify the following informa.docxFind a case study on data mining. Identify the following informa.docx
Find a case study on data mining. Identify the following informa.docx
 
Find 3 sources of information for my research paperAuthors name.docx
Find 3 sources of information for my research paperAuthors name.docxFind 3 sources of information for my research paperAuthors name.docx
Find 3 sources of information for my research paperAuthors name.docx
 
Find 2 case studies that examine an information systems implemen.docx
Find 2 case studies that examine an information systems implemen.docxFind 2 case studies that examine an information systems implemen.docx
Find 2 case studies that examine an information systems implemen.docx
 
Find 2 non-academic sources about your artist, song, or video..docx
Find 2 non-academic sources about your artist, song, or video..docxFind 2 non-academic sources about your artist, song, or video..docx
Find 2 non-academic sources about your artist, song, or video..docx
 
Find 10 different sources for your research paper. These sources sho.docx
Find 10 different sources for your research paper. These sources sho.docxFind 10 different sources for your research paper. These sources sho.docx
Find 10 different sources for your research paper. These sources sho.docx
 

Recently uploaded

Transparency, Recognition and the role of eSealing - Ildiko Mazar and Koen No...
Transparency, Recognition and the role of eSealing - Ildiko Mazar and Koen No...Transparency, Recognition and the role of eSealing - Ildiko Mazar and Koen No...
Transparency, Recognition and the role of eSealing - Ildiko Mazar and Koen No...
EADTU
 
Personalisation of Education by AI and Big Data - Lourdes Guàrdia
Personalisation of Education by AI and Big Data - Lourdes GuàrdiaPersonalisation of Education by AI and Big Data - Lourdes Guàrdia
Personalisation of Education by AI and Big Data - Lourdes Guàrdia
EADTU
 
Spellings Wk 4 and Wk 5 for Grade 4 at CAPS
Spellings Wk 4 and Wk 5 for Grade 4 at CAPSSpellings Wk 4 and Wk 5 for Grade 4 at CAPS
Spellings Wk 4 and Wk 5 for Grade 4 at CAPS
AnaAcapella
 
會考英聽會考英聽會考英聽會考英聽會考英聽會考英聽會考英聽會考英聽會考英聽會考英聽
會考英聽會考英聽會考英聽會考英聽會考英聽會考英聽會考英聽會考英聽會考英聽會考英聽會考英聽會考英聽會考英聽會考英聽會考英聽會考英聽會考英聽會考英聽會考英聽會考英聽
會考英聽會考英聽會考英聽會考英聽會考英聽會考英聽會考英聽會考英聽會考英聽會考英聽
中 央社
 

Recently uploaded (20)

Transparency, Recognition and the role of eSealing - Ildiko Mazar and Koen No...
Transparency, Recognition and the role of eSealing - Ildiko Mazar and Koen No...Transparency, Recognition and the role of eSealing - Ildiko Mazar and Koen No...
Transparency, Recognition and the role of eSealing - Ildiko Mazar and Koen No...
 
24 ĐỀ THAM KHẢO KÌ THI TUYỂN SINH VÀO LỚP 10 MÔN TIẾNG ANH SỞ GIÁO DỤC HẢI DƯ...
24 ĐỀ THAM KHẢO KÌ THI TUYỂN SINH VÀO LỚP 10 MÔN TIẾNG ANH SỞ GIÁO DỤC HẢI DƯ...24 ĐỀ THAM KHẢO KÌ THI TUYỂN SINH VÀO LỚP 10 MÔN TIẾNG ANH SỞ GIÁO DỤC HẢI DƯ...
24 ĐỀ THAM KHẢO KÌ THI TUYỂN SINH VÀO LỚP 10 MÔN TIẾNG ANH SỞ GIÁO DỤC HẢI DƯ...
 
Spring gala 2024 photo slideshow - Celebrating School-Community Partnerships
Spring gala 2024 photo slideshow - Celebrating School-Community PartnershipsSpring gala 2024 photo slideshow - Celebrating School-Community Partnerships
Spring gala 2024 photo slideshow - Celebrating School-Community Partnerships
 
Analyzing and resolving a communication crisis in Dhaka textiles LTD.pptx
Analyzing and resolving a communication crisis in Dhaka textiles LTD.pptxAnalyzing and resolving a communication crisis in Dhaka textiles LTD.pptx
Analyzing and resolving a communication crisis in Dhaka textiles LTD.pptx
 
TỔNG HỢP HƠN 100 ĐỀ THI THỬ TỐT NGHIỆP THPT TOÁN 2024 - TỪ CÁC TRƯỜNG, TRƯỜNG...
TỔNG HỢP HƠN 100 ĐỀ THI THỬ TỐT NGHIỆP THPT TOÁN 2024 - TỪ CÁC TRƯỜNG, TRƯỜNG...TỔNG HỢP HƠN 100 ĐỀ THI THỬ TỐT NGHIỆP THPT TOÁN 2024 - TỪ CÁC TRƯỜNG, TRƯỜNG...
TỔNG HỢP HƠN 100 ĐỀ THI THỬ TỐT NGHIỆP THPT TOÁN 2024 - TỪ CÁC TRƯỜNG, TRƯỜNG...
 
Observing-Correct-Grammar-in-Making-Definitions.pptx
Observing-Correct-Grammar-in-Making-Definitions.pptxObserving-Correct-Grammar-in-Making-Definitions.pptx
Observing-Correct-Grammar-in-Making-Definitions.pptx
 
Personalisation of Education by AI and Big Data - Lourdes Guàrdia
Personalisation of Education by AI and Big Data - Lourdes GuàrdiaPersonalisation of Education by AI and Big Data - Lourdes Guàrdia
Personalisation of Education by AI and Big Data - Lourdes Guàrdia
 
MOOD STABLIZERS DRUGS.pptx
MOOD     STABLIZERS           DRUGS.pptxMOOD     STABLIZERS           DRUGS.pptx
MOOD STABLIZERS DRUGS.pptx
 
Book Review of Run For Your Life Powerpoint
Book Review of Run For Your Life PowerpointBook Review of Run For Your Life Powerpoint
Book Review of Run For Your Life Powerpoint
 
Spellings Wk 4 and Wk 5 for Grade 4 at CAPS
Spellings Wk 4 and Wk 5 for Grade 4 at CAPSSpellings Wk 4 and Wk 5 for Grade 4 at CAPS
Spellings Wk 4 and Wk 5 for Grade 4 at CAPS
 
Đề tieng anh thpt 2024 danh cho cac ban hoc sinh
Đề tieng anh thpt 2024 danh cho cac ban hoc sinhĐề tieng anh thpt 2024 danh cho cac ban hoc sinh
Đề tieng anh thpt 2024 danh cho cac ban hoc sinh
 
When Quality Assurance Meets Innovation in Higher Education - Report launch w...
When Quality Assurance Meets Innovation in Higher Education - Report launch w...When Quality Assurance Meets Innovation in Higher Education - Report launch w...
When Quality Assurance Meets Innovation in Higher Education - Report launch w...
 
diagnosting testing bsc 2nd sem.pptx....
diagnosting testing bsc 2nd sem.pptx....diagnosting testing bsc 2nd sem.pptx....
diagnosting testing bsc 2nd sem.pptx....
 
Graduate Outcomes Presentation Slides - English (v3).pptx
Graduate Outcomes Presentation Slides - English (v3).pptxGraduate Outcomes Presentation Slides - English (v3).pptx
Graduate Outcomes Presentation Slides - English (v3).pptx
 
VAMOS CUIDAR DO NOSSO PLANETA! .
VAMOS CUIDAR DO NOSSO PLANETA!                    .VAMOS CUIDAR DO NOSSO PLANETA!                    .
VAMOS CUIDAR DO NOSSO PLANETA! .
 
ĐỀ THAM KHẢO KÌ THI TUYỂN SINH VÀO LỚP 10 MÔN TIẾNG ANH FORM 50 CÂU TRẮC NGHI...
ĐỀ THAM KHẢO KÌ THI TUYỂN SINH VÀO LỚP 10 MÔN TIẾNG ANH FORM 50 CÂU TRẮC NGHI...ĐỀ THAM KHẢO KÌ THI TUYỂN SINH VÀO LỚP 10 MÔN TIẾNG ANH FORM 50 CÂU TRẮC NGHI...
ĐỀ THAM KHẢO KÌ THI TUYỂN SINH VÀO LỚP 10 MÔN TIẾNG ANH FORM 50 CÂU TRẮC NGHI...
 
會考英聽會考英聽會考英聽會考英聽會考英聽會考英聽會考英聽會考英聽會考英聽會考英聽
會考英聽會考英聽會考英聽會考英聽會考英聽會考英聽會考英聽會考英聽會考英聽會考英聽會考英聽會考英聽會考英聽會考英聽會考英聽會考英聽會考英聽會考英聽會考英聽會考英聽
會考英聽會考英聽會考英聽會考英聽會考英聽會考英聽會考英聽會考英聽會考英聽會考英聽
 
e-Sealing at EADTU by Kamakshi Rajagopal
e-Sealing at EADTU by Kamakshi Rajagopale-Sealing at EADTU by Kamakshi Rajagopal
e-Sealing at EADTU by Kamakshi Rajagopal
 
PSYPACT- Practicing Over State Lines May 2024.pptx
PSYPACT- Practicing Over State Lines May 2024.pptxPSYPACT- Practicing Over State Lines May 2024.pptx
PSYPACT- Practicing Over State Lines May 2024.pptx
 
Mattingly "AI and Prompt Design: LLMs with NER"
Mattingly "AI and Prompt Design: LLMs with NER"Mattingly "AI and Prompt Design: LLMs with NER"
Mattingly "AI and Prompt Design: LLMs with NER"
 

Financial Regulation Lecture 9Based on notes by Marlena El.docx

  • 1. Financial Regulation Lecture 9 Based on notes by Marlena Eley March 22, 2019 1 1 Concept Review We have been studying Cooper and Ross’s paper, which demonstrates how deposit insurance causes moral hazard. Their work uses the Diamond and Dybvig model and adds: 1. Risky Technology 2. Monitoring by Households (HH) The introduction of deposit insurance reduces HH’s incentives to monitor. HHs would have to pay a fixed cost Γ, which is measured in utils (an effort cost rather than a resource cost), to monitor the bank. When HHs do monitor, they are able to FORCE the bank to invest in the safe technology. We know that HHs always prefer the safe long term technology investment to the risky
  • 2. technology investment because they are risk averse (u′′ < 0). 1.1 LEMMA Let q denote the probability of a run - this q is exogenously given. A Bank that maximizes HH’s utility solves the following problem: if q ≤ q∗ the deposit contract offered allows runs if q > q∗ the deposit contract offered is a run preventing contract When q ≤ q∗ , banks are providing liquidity insurance, cE > 1, which means that a run is a potential equilibria. When q > q∗ , banks provide contracts similar to autarky allocations, cE = 1,cL = R. Intuitively, if runs are not very likely, then the bank prefers to offer a contract that allows for runs but offers some liquidity insurance, which is valuable to households. We’re studying when q ≤ q∗ because we want deposit insurance to be offered so that moral hazard is an issue. 1.2 Risky Technology Risky technology is defined as: (−1, 0, { λR with probability ν
  • 3. 0 with probability 1 −ν Where: 1. λ > 1 2. νλ ≤ 1 2 Sidenote: when νλ = 1, we say this technology has a mean preserving spread. Moral hazard is introduced here and this implies that rather than strictly maximizing HH’s utility, Banks are now maximizing profit. The “managers” of the Banks get whatever is leftover after feeding the consumers. Banks then maximize profit as follows: max i∈ [0,1] ν[iλR + (1 − i−πcE)R− (1 −π)cL] + (1 −ν)max(i∗ 0 + (1 − i−πcE)R− (1 −π)cL, 0) We see that the objective function is linear in i which tells us that there may be corner solutions where i∗ = 0 (investment is only made in the safe technology) or i∗ = 1 (investment is only made in the risky technology).
  • 4. 1.3 The Threshold ī We study this decision by establishing a threshold of indifference, ī - when they are indifferent between investing everything in the risky technology and investing in the safe technology. We can establish ī by looking at the investment decision in the low state, (1 −ν) when the risky technology fails. Conditional on being in the low state (1 −ν): ī = {i ∈ [0, 1] : (1 − i−πcE)R− (1 −π)cL = 0} ∀i > ī, (1 − i−πcE)R− (1 −π)cL < 0, max = 0 therefore invests in risky. ∀ i < ī, (1 − i−πcE)R− (1 −π)cL > 0, max = (1 − i−πcE)R− (1 −π)cL therefore invests in safe. Our next step is to plug these values back into the objective function for each case. If i ≥ ī, hence the max = 0, then the objective function becomes: ν[iλR + (1 − i−πcE)R− (1 −π)cL] which is increasing in i ⇒ i∗ = 1 If i < ī, max = (1− i−πcE)R−(1−π)cL and the objective function becomes: ν[iλR + (1 − i−πcE)R− (1 −π)cL] + (1 −ν)[(1 − i−πcE)R− (1 −π)cL] νiλR + (1 − i−πcE)R− (1 −π)cL which is decreasing in i
  • 5. ⇒ i∗ = 0 Now, we need to know which investment strategy results in the higher profit and therefore which investment strategy will be picked? 3 1.3.1 i∗ = 0 Well when i∗ = 0, the profit becomes: (1 −πcE) − (1 −π)cL. We have been solving the Bank’s problem under the assumption that they would be offering the First Best contracts of c sp E and c sp L . We know at the First Best the resource constraint faced by the Social Planner resembles very closely (exactly) the profit of the bank. The resource constraint being: (1 −π)cL = (1 −πcE)R. This then tells us the the Bank’s profit will be 0 when i∗ = 0! 1.3.2 i∗ = 1 Now we have to evaluate the profit when i∗ = 1, which is νλR−πcER− (1 −π)cL. Again, part of this profit, πcER− (1 −π)cL resembles very closely, actually exactly, the Resource
  • 6. Constraint faced by the Social Planner at the First Best solution, where (1 −π)cL = (1 −πcE)R. This then tells us the profit when i∗ = 1 is νλR, which we know is greater than 0! Comparing these two profits, we know that the Bank will invest in the risky technology for the larger profit! This is the risky technology, so i∗ = 1. 2 Monitoring Given what we know: 1. δ = (cE,cL) is the first best allocation and 2. I(cE) and I(cL) are the deposit insurances offered if the bank fails in t=1 and t=2, respectively If the bank is investing in the safe technology, HH won’t monitor. Why would they pay the fixed cost Γ if they know they will get the safe payout? Given we know that the Bank will invest in the risky asset (which we proved in part 1), we want to find the Γ for which a HH will choose to monitor. Remember, by monitoring, HH FORCE the Bank to invest in the safe technology. We can find the Γ for which HH will monitor by finding the following:
  • 7. EUtility without monitoring < E Utility with monitoring 2.1 E (Utility without monitoring) The Expected utility without monitoring is as below: π{(1 −q)[U(cL) + qU(I(cE))}+ (1 −π){[νU(cL) + (1 −ν)U(I(cL))] + qU(I(cE)) Broken down we have: 4 1. π{(1 −q)U(cE) + qU(I(cE))}, which is the expected utility of impatient agents. This multiplies π, the fraction of impatient agents by (1 −q), the probability of no run, times the utility they would get in this equilibria, U(cE), plus q, the probability of a run times the utility they would get in a run U(I(cE)). 2.(1 −π){1 −q)[νU(cL) + (1 −ν)U(I(cL))] + qU(I(cE)), the expected utility of patient agents. This multiplies (1 −π), the fraction of patient agents, by (1 −q), the probability of no run, by the payoff received in no run which is νU(cL) + (1 −ν)U(I(cL)), which itself is an expectation of the payoff based on the success or failure of the risky technology, and q, the probability of a run in t = 1, multiplied by U(I(cE)).
  • 8. 2.2 E(Utility with monitoring) The expected utility with monitoring is as below: −Γ + [π((1 −q)U(cE) + q(I(cE)))] + (1 −π)[(1 −q)U(cL) + qU(I(cE))] Remember, by monitoring and incurring the effort cost Γ, HH force the Bank to invest in safe technology so we don’t even consider payoffs of risky technologies! Broken down we have: 1. π((1 −q)U(cE) + q(I(cE))), which is the utility of impatient agents and 2. (1 −π)[(1 −q)U(cL) + qU(I(cE)), the utility of patient agents. 2.3 E(Utility without monitoring) < E (Utility with monitoring) This inequality is as below: π{(1 −q)[U(cE) + qU(I(cE))} + (1 −π){(1 −q)[νU(cL) + (1 −ν)U(I(cL))] + qU(I(cE))}≤−Γ+[π((1−q)U(cE)+q(I(cE)))]+(1−π)[(1−q)U(cL)+q U(I(cE))] This equation greatly simplifies, namely terms for early consumers cancel out, which makes sense as they withdraw at t = 1 anyway so they don’t care about whether the bank invests in the risk technology (they are not around at t = 2 anyway as they consume before and their preferences are not defined over
  • 9. consumption at t = 2). 1 In other words, if the bank invests in risky technologies, they are not the ones who face an insolvent bank. This then simplifies to: (1 −π){(1 −q)[νU(cL) + (1 −ν)U(I(cL))]}≤−Γ{(1 −π)[(1 −q)U(cL)]} ⇒ Γ ≤ (1 −π)(1 −q)(1 −ν)[U(cL) −U(I(cL))] Here the tradeoff between deposit insurance and monitoring is greatly apparent, look at the term U(cL) −U(I(cL))! 1This is equivalent to saying they exit the economy, for our purposes. 5 So far, we have been considering deposit insurance to be complete, that is that I(cL) = cL. If this is the case then, Γ < 0 for HH to monitor the banks! Therefore monitor will never take place under complete deposit insurance for any value of Γ > 0. 2.4 Finding Γ Well, lets try to figure out if there is a way to have HH monitor AND still implement the First Best allocation.
  • 10. Let’s consider the assumptions that we’re making: 1. cL = c sp L 2. If there was no insurance at all monitoring would take place if we make the following assumption: Γ ≤ (1 −π)(1 −q)(1 −ν)U(cspL ) Now we have to consider whether we can implement the first best allocation. Well, if we do, there is a potential for a run equilibrium and HH will monitor. But by monitoring, HH incur the cost Γ and there is a potential for a run. Well, what happens with complete deposit insurance? HH don’t monitor and Banks end up investing in risky technology. HH are paid even in the event of a run or a Bank failure. Can the First Best be implemented in this situation? The solution offered by Cooper and Ross is Capital Requirements. They suggest that if Banks are solely gambling with depositors money what would happen if Banks were forced to invest some of their own resources? 3 Capital Requirements In the case of Capital Requirements we have to make an additional
  • 11. assumption. 1. Banks’ shareholders have ”deep pockets” This just says that Banks get some money from outside the model. These shareholders have a large endowment of the good. Cooper and Ross then introduce Capital Requirements which require banks to invest at least K units of their own endowment per unit of deposit. With the introduction of Capital Requirements the Banks problem becomes: max i∈ [0,1+K] {ν[iλR + (1 + K − i−πcE)R− (1 −π)cL] + (1 −ν)max((1 + K − i−πcE)R− (1 −π)cL, 0)} 6 We solve this the exact same way that we solved the previous problem! ∀ī ∈ [0, 1 + K] such that the payoff in the low state is the same regardless whether the bank is solvent or not. (1 + K − ī−πcE)R− (1 −π)cL = 0 ∀ (1 + K − ī−πcE)R = (1 −πcL)
  • 12. For i ≥ ī: max (1 + K − ī−πcE)R− (1 −π)cL, 0) = 0 ⇒ i∗ = 1 + K (invest in the risky technology) For i ≤ ī ⇒ i∗ = 0 (invest only in the safe technology) The question then becomes, is there a value of K such that the First Best allocation can be implemented as an equilibrium outcome? 3.1 Finding K There are three steps to finding this K: 1. Use the First Best allocation 2. Evaluate the Bank’s profit from investing all in safe or all in risky technology 3. Solve for the smallest K such that i = 0 (investment in all safe technology) yields the highest profit. Solving for K in this way is solving for the minimum capital requirement necessary for the bank to be indifferent between investing in risky technologies and safe technologies. We know how to solve this: we evaluate the investment strategies at the two corners! Step 1 - First Best Allocation c sp E > 1 ⇒ c
  • 13. sp L < R From the resource constraint at the First Best, (1 −π)cspL = R(1 −πc sp E ) Step 2 - The Bank’s Payoffs max i∈ [0,1+K] ν[iλR + (1 + K − i−πcE)R− (1 −π)cL] + (1 −ν)max((1 + K − i−πcE)R− (1 −π)cL, 0) Plugging in the Resource Constraint for (1 −π)cL = R(1 −πcE), this simplifies to: max i∈ [0,1+K] {ν[iλR + (K − i)R] + (1 −ν)max((K − i)R, 0)} The payoff at i = 0 is then KR. The payoff at i = 1 + K is then ν[(1 + K)λR−R]. 7 Step 3 - Finding the Smallest K This then sets us up with the inequality KR ≥ ν[(1 + K)λR−R], from which
  • 14. we can solve for a K. KR = ν[(1 + K)λR−R] KR = ν(1 + K)λR−νR K = νλ + νKλ−ν K −νλK = νλ−ν K(1 −νλ) = ν(λ− 1) ∴ K = ν(λ− 1) (1 −νλ) For K = ν(λ−1) (1−νλ) , there is no monitoring AND we are implementing the First Best allocation! We are disciplining the moral hazard by implementing these Capital Requirements. Because we know what λ and ν are, we can talk about how K changes when the technology becomes riskier. 3.2 How K Changes with λ and ν If we assume that the risky technology has a mean preserving spread, i.e. λ̂ν̂ = λν and λ̂ > λ (the technology has higher returns) and ν̂ < ν (the technology has a lower probability of success), then: K ̂ = ν̂λ̂−ν̂ 1−ν̂λ̂
  • 15. = λν−ν̂ 1−λν ∀ K ̂ > K This tells us that the riskier the technology, the higher the capital requirement needed to discipline the moral hazard and implement the First Best allocation. 8 Institute of Social and Economic Research, Osaka University Bank Runs: Deposit Insurance and Capital Requirements Author(s): Russell Cooper and Thomas W. Ross Source: International Economic Review, Vol. 43, No. 1 (Feb., 2002), pp. 55-72 Published by: Wiley for the Economics Department of the University of Pennsylvania and Institute of Social and Economic Research, Osaka University Stable URL: https://www.jstor.org/stable/827056 Accessed: 30-03-2019 02:57 UTC JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide
  • 16. range of content in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and facilitate new forms of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact [email protected] Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available at https://about.jstor.org/terms Wiley, Institute of Social and Economic Research, Osaka University are collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend access to International Economic Review This content downloaded from 141.161.91.14 on Sat, 30 Mar 2019 02:57:00 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms INTERNATIONAL ECONOMIC REVIEW Vol. 43, No. 1, February 2002 BANK RUNS: DEPOSIT INSURANCE AND CAPITAL REQUIREMENTS* BY RUSSELL COOPER AND THOMAS W. ROSS1 Boston University, U.S.A. and University of British Columbia, Canada
  • 17. Diamond and Dybvig provide a model of intermediation in which deposit insurance can avoid socially undesirable bank runs. We extend the Diamond- Dybvig model to evaluate the costs and benefits of deposit insurance in the presence of moral hazard by banks and monitoring by depositors. We find that complete deposit insurance alone will not support the first-best outcome: de- positors will not have adequate incentives for monitoring and banks will invest in excessively risky projects. However, an additional capital requirement for banks can restore the first-best allocation. 1. INTRODUCTION The publicly supported deposit insurance plans of a number of countries, most notably the United States and Canada, have recently come under intense public scrutiny as concerns have mounted about the substantial contingent liabilities they have created for taxpayers. In the United States the savings and loan (S&L) crisis led to the transfer of a huge amount of bad debt, estimated recently at about $130 billion, onto taxpayers' shoulders.2 Created originally to support the banking sector by building depositor confidence, there is recognition that the insurance provided by * Manuscript received November 1998; revised October 1999. 1This is a considerably expanded version of Section IV of our NBER Working Paper, #3921,
  • 18. November 1991. We have benefited from discussions on this topic with Paul Beaudry, Fanny Demers, Jon Eaton, Alok Johri, Arthur Rolnick, Thomas Rymes, Fabio Schiantarelli, David Weil, and Steven Williamson, and from helpful comments received from seminar participants at Boston University, Brown University, Carleton University, the Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis, the University of British Columbia, and the University of Maryland. The extensive comments provided by three referees and the editor of this journal are gratefully acknowledged. Financial support for this work came from the National Science Foundation, the SFU-UBC Centre for the Study of Government and Business, and the Social Sciences and Humanities Research Council of Canada. The first author is grateful to the Institute for Empirical Macroeconomics at the Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis for providing a productive working environment during preparation of parts of this manuscript. Some of this work was done while the second author was visiting the Canadian Competition Bureau and he is grateful for the Bureau's assistance. The views expressed here are not necessarily those of the Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis or of the Canadian Competition Bureau. Please address correspondence to: Russell Cooper, Department of Economics, Boston University, 270 Bay State Road, Boston, MA 02215. Fax: 617-353-4449. E-mail: [email protected] 2 There is a considerable literature on the S&L crisis; see, for example, Feldstein (1991), Kormendi et al. (1989), and White (1991).
  • 19. 55 This content downloaded from 141.161.91.14 on Sat, 30 Mar 2019 02:57:00 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms COOPER AND ROSS these plans has encouraged excessive risk taking by financial intermediaries.3 These concerns have led to calls for the reform of deposit insurance and even suggestions that it be abolished. This paper attempts to evaluate the trade-offs between risk sharing and moral hazard associated with the design of banking regulations. In particular, we focus on two policy instruments: deposit insurance and bank capital requirements. We are interested in how these instruments can be used (and misused) to control bank runs in an envi- ronment in which banks can make imprudent investments and depositors can monitor bank behavior. Reflecting ongoing problems in the financial services sector, there has been a great deal of research recently on lending behavior, bank stability, and optimal banking regulation. While a number of publications have considered parts of the problem addressed here, no individual contribution tackles the joint determination of optimal
  • 20. deposit insurance and capital requirements within a bank runs model with risk- averse depositors, depositor monitoring, and moral hazard.4 Given the ongoing public debate over deposit insurance and capital requirements and the attention paid to the supposed trade-off between bank runs and moral hazard, a structure is needed that contains these elements. With its emphasis on bank runs, the model of Diamond and Dybvig (1983) provides a convenient starting point for studying these issues. In the absence of any moral hazard considerations, Diamond and Dybvig argue that publicly provided deposit insurance can be effective as protection against expectations-driven bank runs.5 However, their 3 Deposit insurance was created in the United States during the Great Depression (1934) to restore depositor confidence. It came to Canada in 1967. Concerns about the Canadian system are expressed in Smith and White (1988). 4 Some of this literature is reviewed in the recent books by Dewatripont and Tirole (1994) and Freixas and Rochet (1997). The articles closest in purpose to this one include Giammarino et al. (1993), Matutes and Vives (1996), Besanko and Kanatas (1993), Holmstrom and Tirole (1993), Kupiec and O'Brien (1997), and Peck and Shell (1999). Each considers some aspect of our problem, but none combines the elements we view as important here. For example, Giammarino et al. (1993) consider optimal deposit insurance premia in markets with bank
  • 21. moral hazard but no bank runs. Matutes and Vives (1996) study the effect of competition on bank fragility with deposit insurance. Besanko and Kanatas (1993) consider the provision of funds to firms from both banks (through loans) and capital markets in a model with bank moral hazard but no bank runs. Studying bank lending behavior (without deposits or bank runs), Holmstrom and Tirole (1993) find that borrower moral hazard can be controlled by requiring that borrowers contribute some of their own funds-a requirement not unlike the capital requirements that banks face. Finally, Peck and Shell (1999) also examine policies that might influence the probability of bank runs, but focus on deposit contracts that permit the suspension of convertibility and on government restrictions on banks' portfolios of loans. 5 Further, Wallace (1988) has argued that there is an inconsistency in the Diamond-Dybvig model's treatment of deposit insurance. The spatial separation that motivates banking appears inconsistent with the ability of governments to provide deposit insurance. However, Wallace goes on to point out that "...this argument does not say that any kind of deposit insurance is infeasible. It only says that the policy that Diamond and Dybvig identify with deposit insurance is infeasible..." (p. 13). We are in complete agreement; clearly the financing of deposit insurance must be credible to eliminate certain equilibria. Therefore, in contrast to Diamond and Dybvig, we rely on the presence of an outside group of agents ("taxpayers") as a tax base. Essentially, the government has enough information to tax labor income without needing to overcome any spatial separation constraints.
  • 22. 56 This content downloaded from 141.161.91.14 on Sat, 30 Mar 2019 02:57:00 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms DEPOSIT INSURANCE AND INCENTIVES model does not incorporate the moral hazard considerations seen to be central to recent policy debates. Deposit insurance avoids bank runs but has adverse incentive effects: it implies less monitoring by depositors, which allows banks to hold riskier portfolios. In fact, if deposit insurance is complete enough, depositors' and banks' interests are aligned: both types of agents are eager to hold high-risk portfolios, effectively gambling with taxpayers' money. Thus a trade-off emerges between providing insurance against bank runs and monitoring incentives. By characterizing this trade-off, our model permits a derivation of the optimal degree of deposit insurance. In general, deposit insurance with depositor monitoring is not sufficient to support the first-best outcome. However, appropriately designed capital requirements can eliminate the incentive problem caused by deposit insur- ance and support the first-best allocation.
  • 23. From the perspective of our model, the experience in the U.S. during the 1980s suggests two forms of regulatory failure. First, capital requirements were inadequate. Second, the relaxation of Regulation Q allowed banks to more aggressively compete for deposits, which, along with deposit insurance, led to excessively risky investment. This is certainly not a novel story but one that appears here in a consistent, formal framework. 2. MODEL The model is a modified version of Diamond-Dybvig (1983). There are N, ex ante identical, agents in the economy who are each born with a unit endow- ment, which they deposit with an intermediary in period 0.6 At the start of period 1, agents are informed about their taste types. A fraction r learn that they obtain utility from period 1 consumption only (early consumers), while the others obtain utility exclusively from period 2 consumption (late consumers). As in the first part of Diamond and Dybvig (1983), assume that n is nonstochastic and known to all agents.7 Denote by CE and CL the consumption levels for early and late con- sumers, respectively, and let U(c) represent their utility function over consump- tion. Assume that U(') is strictly increasing and strictly concave, U'(0)= oo, and U(0) =0. There are two technologies available for transferring resources
  • 24. over time. First, there is a productive technology that is not completely liquid. This technology provides a means of shifting resources from period 0 to 2, with a return of R > 1 over the two periods. However, liquidation of projects using this technique yields only one unit in period 1 per unit of period 0 investment. Second, there is a storage tech- nology, available to both intermediaries and consumers, that yields one unit in 6 In Cooper and Ross (1998) we allow consumers to make their own investments rather than using an intermediary and prove that using an intermediary in this structure always weakly dominates autarky. 7 In the last part of their article they consider the importance of aggregate uncertainty to argue further in favor of deposit insurance instead of policies that suspend convertibility. 57 This content downloaded from 141.161.91.14 on Sat, 30 Mar 2019 02:57:00 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms COOPER AND ROSS period t + 1 per unit of period t investment, t = 0, 1. While not as productive as the
  • 25. illiquid technology over two periods, storage provides the same one-period return.8 The intermediary operates in a competitive environment, which compels it to offer contracts that maximize consumers' ex ante expected utility subject to a break-even constraint. If the ex post consumer taste types were costlessly verifiable it would therefore offer a contract 6* = (c, cL) solving (1) max 7rU(cE) + (1 - 7)U(cL) CE,CL (1 - 7)cL s.t. 1 = CE +1 From the first-order conditions, the optimal contract satisfies (2) U'(c) = RU'(cL) Since R > 1, the strict concavity of U(.) implies that cE < c4 for (2) to hold. Diamond and Dybvig establish that when consumer tastes are private information, multiple equilibria may exist. The contracting problem can be formulated with three stages. First, the contract is set by the intermediary, which specifies a consumption level for each type of consumer independent of the number of consumers claiming to be each type.9 Second, agents learn their preferences and these are announced to the intermediary. Finally, the allocation of goods to agents is determined by the contract. The first-best outcome with the contract b* will be one
  • 26. equilibrium of this game. Truth telling is a dominant strategy for early consumers while truth telling by late consumers is a best response to truth telling by all other late consumers. Under b* there may also exist an equilibrium in which all late consumers mis- represent their tastes and announce that they are early consumers. This can be an equilibrium if the intermediary does not have sufficient resources (including liqui- dated illiquid investments) to provide cE to all agents. As in the Diamond-Dybvig model, the late consumers who do not withdraw in period 1 obtain a pro rata share of the bank's period 2 assets. This equilibrium with misrepresentation is termed a "bank run." The first-best allocation is vulnerable to runs iff cE > 1: otherwise, the interme- diary would have sufficient resources to meet the demand of cE by all agents in period 1. Diamond and Dybvig (1983) show that if agents are sufficiently risk averse, then cE will exceed 1. 8 In this setup, which comes from Diamond and Dybvig, returns on investments made in this productive technology are always (weakly) greater than those in the alternative (storage). In Cooper and Ross (1998) we extend the model by adding a liquidation cost to these illiquid projects that
  • 27. renders the one-period return to liquidated investments less than the alternative. This expands the set of conditions under which bank runs can occur and influences agents' investment and contract choices. It does not, however, have implications for the results described below so we have chosen to work with the simpler model here. 9 Thus, in particular, it is not feasible for the bank to accumulate information about withdrawals and make payments to depositors contingent on this information. Further, agents are unable to meet at a common location after period 0, thus eliminating the types of ex post markets considered in, for example, Jacklin (1987). 58 This content downloaded from 141.161.91.14 on Sat, 30 Mar 2019 02:57:00 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms DEPOSIT INSURANCE AND INCENTIVES As described in Alonso (1996) and Cooper and Ross (1991, 1998), there are essentially two ways the intermediary can optimally respond to the possibility of multiple equilibria. One is to find the best contract available that is not vulnerable to runs. This best runs-preventing contract comes from solving (1) with the added constraint CE < 1 so that there are always sufficient resources available in period 1 to
  • 28. pay all consumers. Concavity arguments demonstrate that if the first-best contract is vulnerable to runs (i.e., c3 > 1), the best runs-preventing contract will involve CE= 1 and CL = R. As an alternative, one might construct a model of the equilibrium selection pro- cess and solve for the optimal contract. One simple model relies on the existence of publicly observable, but not contractible, variables (sunspots) that correlate agents' behavior at a particular equilibrium of the game.10 Instead of preventing runs, the intermediary adjusts the contract to reduce the impact of runs in the event they arise. Suppose that with probability q there is a wave of economy- wide pessimism that determines the beliefs of depositors. If the outstanding contract has a runs equilib- rium the pessimism leads to a bank run. With probability (1 - q), there is optimism and no run occurs. In this way, the beliefs of depositors are tied to a move of nature that determines their actions. The intermediary recognizes this dependence in de- signing the optimal contract. Taking the probability of liquidation, q, as given, the contract solves (assuming CE> 1) (3) max(1 - q)[nU(cE) + (1 - m)U(CL)] + qU(cE)(1/cE) CE,CL
  • 29. (1 - t)cL s.t. 1 = 7cE + - Let 6(q) be the contract solving this problem.1 Cooper and Ross (1998) show the existence of a critical q* C (0, 1) such that the best runs- preventing contract domi- nates the best contract with runs if q > q* and the reverse holds if q < q*. 3. SUPPORTING THE FIRST-BEST: DEPOSIT INSURANCE AND CAPITAL REQUIREMENTS The previous section characterizes the optimal response of a private bank facing the prospect of a run. Regardless of whether the intermediary optimally adopts a runs-preventing contract or allows runs, the possibility of bank runs clearly lowers expected utility below that attainable in the first-best solution. This naturally raises 10 Bental et al. (1990) and Freeman (1988) also adopt a sunspots approach. In contrast to our work, those articles allow for sunspot-contingent contracts. While it is convenient to think of sunspots as determining which equilibrium of the subgame will be observed, contracts contingent on these events are assumed to be infeasible. 1 Here an agent receives CE with probability liCE in the event of a run, which occurs with probability q. Note that if the solution to (3) involved CE < 1 it would in fact be runs-preventing and therefore be dominated by the best runs-preventing contract
  • 30. (CE = 1 and CL = R). 59 This content downloaded from 141.161.91.14 on Sat, 30 Mar 2019 02:57:00 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms COOPER AND ROSS the question of whether some government intervention in the form of deposit in- surance or other instrument could prevent runs and thus improve welfare.12 Deposit insurance is a contract set by the government that provides a payment to depositors in the event that the bank is unable to meet its obligations.13 Diamond and Dybvig argue that a simple deposit insurance scheme will eliminate bank runs in their model. However, their argument leaves aside the adverse incentive effects of deposit insurance on both the investment strategy of the intermediary and the monitoring decisions of depositors. We study this by adding both moral hazard and monitoring by depositors to our model. Our main result in this section is that an appropriately designed capital requirement coupled with deposit insurance can avoid bank runs without creating severe moral hazard problems. 3.1. Extended Model. We modify the basic model in a number
  • 31. of ways, detailed in the subsections that follow. First, we introduce a richer investment choice for the banks. Second, we allow for a monitoring decision by depositors. Third, we introduce both deposit insurance and capital requirements as policy instruments for the gov- ernment. The sequence of events in period 0 is as follows: First, the government sets a deposit insurance policy. In general, the government contract stipulates payments to early and late consumers as a function of the deposit contract in the event the intermediary is unable to make its promised payments. We denote the payments to early and late consumers as I(CE) and I(CL) respectively. Since the government is unable to observe the types of private agents, it too must rely on the agents' an- nouncements. Put differently, those agents who appear at the intermediary in period 1 are termed early consumers and are eligible for the government insurance over CE in the event the intermediary is unable to meet its obligations. Likewise, an agent who makes the announcement of being a late consumer is eligible for government insurance over CL if the bank fails in period 2. Importantly, if a bank fails in period 1, then late consumers will not receive insurance over CL. Instead, they will receive the same payment as early consumers if a bank fails in period 1. Note that we assume that government insurance policy depends on the deposit
  • 32. contract offered by the intermediary. Second, the competitive banks offer a contract, 6. Depositors then decide on the allocation of their endowment and whether to monitor the bank. If the bank 12 For the purposes of this exercise, we do not consider private deposit insurance schemes. 13 For simplicity, assume that the tax obligations to finance deposit insurance fall upon agents who are not depositors. Hence we do not consider the possibility that intermediaries make payments into a deposit insurance pool but rather focus on the obligations of taxpayers to the system. Here we imagine a government policy that provides deposit insurance to agents who arrive at the bank after the bank has exhausted resources and then taxes, say, the endowment of a group of agents in the economy not involved with the intermediary or even the endowment of the next generation of depositors, as in Freeman (1988), to finance these transfers. We assume that the social welfare function is such that providing this insurance is desirable. The key point is that there must be a government taxation scheme that is not inconsistent with isolation that is capable of generating the needed revenues. 60 This content downloaded from 141.161.91.14 on Sat, 30 Mar 2019 02:57:00 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
  • 33. DEPOSIT INSURANCE AND INCENTIVES is monitored, investment decisions are observable to all agents. The depositors then learn their taste types. Finally, the bank manager allocates the funds to the two investments. Our choice of timing here is not very restrictive: the outcome of this model and that with simultaneous moves by the monitor(s) and the banker are the same though it is important that the monitoring occurs before the types are realized. 3.1.1. Richer technology. To allow the bank an avenue for moral hazard, as- sume that there exists a second, multiperiod technology that yields a second period return of 2R with probability v and 0 otherwise. Further, assume that 2 > 1 and v2 < 1 so that this risky technique has a higher return if it is successful but a lower expected return than the riskless illiquid investment. Thus, the riskless two-period investment is preferred to the risky illiquid investment by all risk averters.14 As with the riskless illiquid technology, this alternative technology also yields one unit in period 1 per unit invested in period 0. The bank's investment policy is chosen by a risk-neutral manager who represents the bank's owners (shareholders). We assume that any funds
  • 34. remaining after the payment of cL to the late consumers are retained by the shareholders of the bank. As before, if the intermediary does not have sufficient funds for the late consumers, then these agents (and not the shareholders) have rights to a pro rata share of the bank's resources. As we shall see, under some contracts, the manager may have an incentive to invest using the risky technology. In particular, in the absence of a minimum capital requirement, the risky investment is preferred by the manager since 2 > 1 gives him (i.e., the shareholders) a chance at a high return.15 When deposit insurance is suf- ficiently generous, depositors will not care that the bank undertakes risky invest- ments. More formally, suppose that the bank offered depositors the first-best contract 6* and that the government provides depositors with complete deposit insurance; i.e., I(cL)= CL. Let i denote the amount of resources (per unit of deposit) that the in- termediary places in the risky illiquid investment. Then i is chosen to max[v(i2R + (1 - i - nrc)R - (1 - n)c) + (1 - v)max((1 - i- rc* )R - (1 - n)cj, 0)] The max operator appears here since the bank may not have enough resources to meet the needs of depositors when the risky investment fails.
  • 35. Since the inter- mediary earns zero profits in the first-best contract when it invests all of its funds in the riskless illiquid technology, for any i > 0, the intermediary has zero return in the state in which the risky investment fails. Further, with vA < 1, the inter- mediary's expected return is positive and increasing in i. Thus the solution is for the intermediary to place all funds in the risky illiquid investment. Since 14 That is, vU(RX) + (1 - v)U(O) < U(vRA) < U(R) for any concave U(.). 15 "For example, if a bank's liabilities are deposits insured with fixed-rate Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation (FDIC) insurance, it is well known that the bank may have an incentive to select very risky assets since the deposit insurers bear the brunt of downside risk but the bank owners get the benefit of the upside risk" (Diamond and Dybvig, 1986, p. 59). 61 This content downloaded from 141.161.91.14 on Sat, 30 Mar 2019 02:57:00 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms COOPER AND ROSS depositors receive full deposit insurance, they have no
  • 36. incentive to oppose this investment strategy. 3.1.2. Depositor monitoring. The second change to our model is the inclusion of a monitoring decision on the part of depositors. Any depositor who monitors incurs a cost r (modeled as a utility loss) and can force the bank to adopt the depositor's desired portfolio.16 Given the moral hazard problem outlined above, depositor monitoring is a potentially important element in overcoming the incentive of banks to invest in risky ventures. We begin the analysis by studying the monitoring decisions by the depositors given the investment choices by the manager, the level of deposit insurance provided by the government, and a deposit contract, (CE, CL). We consider here the case of a single depositor, but the qualitative results can be extended to the multidepositor case.17 If the bank has an incentive to invest in the risky technique, then monitoring will occur iff (4) (1 - 7r)(1 - v)(1 - q)[U(cL)- U(I(cL))] > r The left-hand side is the expected gain to the depositor from turning the problem into one of full information for a given value of CL and the right-hand side is the monitoring cost. Note that this condition incorporates the assertion that if moni- toring did not occur, the bank would invest in the risky
  • 37. technology that would yield the depositor CL with probability v. Further, as the monitoring decision is made in period 0, the individual values the information only if he is a late consumer, which happens with probability (1 - n). Finally, the gains to monitoring are lost if there is a bank run since both the risky and riskless illiquid techniques generate equal returns over the first period. So, the left-hand side of (4) includes (1 - q), the probability of optimism. The influence of deposit insurance on monitoring is apparent from this condition. If I(CL) is close to CL for all levels of late consumption, then the single agent has no incentive to monitor. However, for small levels of insurance, monitoring will take place. For this analysis, we assume that when there is no deposit insurance, a single depositor will monitor if CL = CL. 16 Calomiris and Kahn (1991) model monitoring as a private activity though the outcome of monitoring is made public. The incentives to monitor are created by sequential service in which the agents who monitor are "first in line." Our results are robust to assuming that the information generated by monitoring is private. 17 The existence of multiple depositors creates a number of interesting complications due to free riding on the monitoring of others. One possibility of resolving this is via a cooperative
  • 38. agreement on monitoring: an accounting firm is retained as part of the deposit arrangement. Alternatively, in the noncooperative game between depositors to determine the level of monitoring by each, there will be asymmetric equilibria in which one depositor monitors and the others free ride. There may also be equilibria in which monitoring costs are shared by a subset of the depositors. Finally, there may also be a mixed-strategy equilibrium that each agent monitors with some probability. Such a model is considered in an expanded version of this article available from the authors. 62 This content downloaded from 141.161.91.14 on Sat, 30 Mar 2019 02:57:00 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms DEPOSIT INSURANCE AND INCENTIVES 3.2. Capital Requirements. Consider a second instrument of government policy: a requirement on the ratio of debt to equity financing for an intermediary. To be precise, suppose that the shareholders of the intermediary are required by the government to contribute K units of the numeraire good per unit of deposit to the intermediary's capital account. Let i again denote the funds (per unit of deposit) that the intermediary places in
  • 39. the risky investment. Then the portfolio choice of the intermediary is determined from (5) max[v(i2R + ((K + 1) - i - 7cE)R - (1 - 7)CL) + (1 - v) max((1 + K - i - 7CE)R - (1 - 7t)CL, 0)] The first part of this expression applies to the case of a successful risky invest- ment outcome, in which case the shareholders of the bank earn a high return of AR on the i units placed into the risky illiquid investment. With probability (1 - v), however, the risky investment fails and the bank's resources are limited to (1 + K -i- - i CE), which earns a return of R. These funds are then used to meet the demands of late consumers, given by (1 - 7t)CL. It is possible that the intermediary does not have sufficient resources to meet these demands by late consumers so that the bank's shareholders obtain 0. Hence the max operator in (5). In fact, the nonlinearity created by the possibility of bankruptcy is central to the moral hazard problem faced by a bank. In particular, suppose that the terms of the contract offered depositors are such that there exists a level of risky illiquid in- vestment (i') satisfying (1 + K - i' - 7CE)R = (1 - 7)CL
  • 40. At this critical level of risky investment, the firm has zero profits in the second period when the risky project fails. It is easy to see that the expected payoff of the intermediary is higher at i = 0 than for any i c (0, i') since shareholders bear all of the downside risk from investing more resources in the risky illiquid project for i in this interval. For any i > i', shareholders do not bear the risk of this investment, so it is profitable to put more funds in the risky investment. Thus, from this optimization problem, the choice of the intermediary is reduced to placing either all of the funds in the risky investment or all of the funds in the riskless investment. 3.3. Supporting the First-Best Allocation. The point of the following proposi- tion is that if the capital requirement is sufficiently large, shareholders will no longer prefer to gamble with depositors' funds and thus the moral hazard problem is solved. Further, with complete deposit insurance, bank runs are eliminated. Finally, depositors will have no need to monitor the bank since they are completely insured. 63 This content downloaded from 141.161.91.14 on Sat, 30 Mar 2019 02:57:00 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
  • 41. COOPER AND ROSS Formally: PROPOSITION 1. If I(CL) = CL for CL < C, I(CL) = CL for CL > C, I(CE) = CE for CE < CE, I(CE) = CE for CE > CE, and K > K* - [v(2 - 1)]/[1 - 2v], then the first-best allocation of (c , cL) is achievable without bank runs and without monitoring. PROOF. Since deposit insurance is complete up to (c4, cL), if the first-best con- tract is offered, bank runs will be eliminated. Using the first-best contract, (5) becomes (6) max[v(i)R + ((K + 1) - i - rcc)R - (1 - n)c*) + (1 - v) max((1 + K - i - rnc)R - (1 - n)c*, 0)] Using the resource constraint of R = (1 - n)c4 + R7rc, this reduces to (7) max[v(i2R + (K - i)R) + (1 - v) max((K - i)R, 0)] Clearly, i will be set to 0 or to its maximal value of (1 + K) since any interior choice of i is dominated by one of these extremes. The profits of the intermediary are higher at i=O than at i = 1 + K iff RK > v(l + K)XR - Rv
  • 42. which reduces to the condition given in the proposition. Finally, from the definition of the first-best, there is no other contract that can increase the expected utility of the consumer. Thus, if capital requirements meet the bound given in the proposition, banks will offer the first-best contract to depositors and will not have any incentive to invest in the risky technology. Depositors will therefore have no incentive to monitor and, given the presence of complete deposit insurance, there will be no bank runs. i The point of this proposition is that an adequate equity capital base can provide sufficient incentive to owners managers to overcome the moral hazard problems without the need for monitoring by depositors. In this case, deposit insurance can prevent bank runs without creating incentive problems and the first-best allocation, given as the solution to (2), can be supported.18 Note that the capital requirement does not specify how the intermediary must invest the funds that shareholders provide. In the proof of Proposition 1, we find that if the intermediary has an incentive to invest depositors' funds in the risky illiquid technology (which occurs iff K < K*), then the intermediary will invest shareholders' funds in the risky venture as well. If it did not do so, the intermediary would be forced to pay depositors all of the shareholders' funds in the event that the risky
  • 43. venture failed. Hence the incentive to gamble with depositors' funds will spill over to the allocation of shareholders' funds as well. 18 As a referee has correctly pointed out, the assumption of risk neutrality on the part of the bank is important to this result. If the bank manager and shareholders were risk averse, there would be additional costs associated with investing own-capital in a bank with uncertain returns. 64 This content downloaded from 141.161.91.14 on Sat, 30 Mar 2019 02:57:00 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms DEPOSIT INSURANCE AND INCENTIVES The effects of parameter changes on the critical level of capital K* are of interest. For example, a mean-preserving spread on the returns from the risky asset, as rep- resented by a combination of increasing i and decreasing v that leaves 2v constant, will increase K*. That is, as the probability of the risky asset succeeding falls, holding the expected return constant, more capital will be needed to deter morally hazardous investment behavior. This is a fairly intuitive result. However, if we increase either i or v while holding the other fixed-in either case increasing the efficiency of the risky investment-the minimum capital requirement actually rises. As
  • 44. the risky asset is more attractive, we need to impose tighter minimum capital requirements. 4. THE SAVINGS AND LOAN CRISIS The model developed here is also useful in understanding the role that sub- optimal regulatory policies played in the S&L crisis in the United States in the 1980s.19 This crisis, almost certainly one of the most important events in American banking history, has imposed costs on taxpayers that continue to mount. In the late 1970s and early 1980s interest rates climbed substantially, and S&Ls and some banks were squeezed as depositors withdrew funds to put them into higher-yielding Treasury Bills and money market funds while the long-term mortgages that provided much of the S&L income were fixed at interest rates far below market rates. Regulatory reforms introduced to help S&Ls compete (e.g., flexible rate mortgages), the relaxation of controls on interest rates paid (Regu- lation Q), and the expansion of deposit insurance protection combined with a lack of regulatory oversight to introduce severe problems of moral hazard. Thrifts with low levels of net worth now had the opportunity to gamble with other people's (i.e., taxpayers') money and insured depositors had little incentive to
  • 45. monitor their thrifts. Indeed, if taxpayers were going to cover the downside, depositors shared the thrift owners' interest in risky investments with high upside potential, even if the expected yield was low. For a time, this strategy led to rapid growth of S&Ls, but eventually the poor quality of their investments brought many down. To see how our model can explain important aspects of the S&L crisis, we focus on two key aspects of White's (1991) description of the S&L crisis: (i) the removal of Regulation Q and (ii) the inadequacy of capital requirements. Removing Regulation Q allowed banks more flexibility in competing for depositors, that is, greater latitude in setting CE and CL. One view of Regulation Q was that it essentially mandated runs- preventing contracts, and its repeal allowed banks to offer contracts that were vul- nerable to runs. When squeezed by the new pressure to offer higher interest rates to attract deposits even while many of their loans (often mortgages) were set at very low rates, many smaller institutions became seriously undercapitalized-a deficiency not 19 For background on the crisis and its causes, see, for example, White (1991), Grossman (1992), and Dewatripont and Tirole (1994, Chapter 4). 65 This content downloaded from 141.161.91.14 on Sat, 30 Mar
  • 46. 2019 02:57:00 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms COOPER AND ROSS always noticed by regulators failing to measure the values of assets at current market prices.20 While the inadequate capitalization may have changed the incentives of banks to avoid risky projects, the existence of deposit insurance implied that depositors were still willing to place funds in these institutions. It is important to recognize that, in our model, deposit insurance does not create the moral hazard problem: the manager's interest in the risky asset would exist in the absence of insurance. What the deposit insurance does is reduce the incentive of depositors to monitor banks. In the case of many of the failed S&Ls, the interests of these agents became aligned with those of the banks and jointly they gambled with taxpayers' money.21 To formalize this point, we consider the implications of suboptimal deposit in- surance and inadequate capital requirements. In particular, we assume that no capital requirements are in place. This assumption simplifies the analysis and captures the theme that a key aspect of this experience was
  • 47. inadequate capital requirements. While outside our model, one could imagine that a period of de- flation led to a reduction in the value of capital and thus the inadequacy of existing capital requirements.22 Further, we consider a relatively simple deposit insurance scheme, in which the government provides a fraction c of the resources owed to depositors (both early and/or late types) when a bank fails.23 In particular, recall that we assume that if a bank fails in period 1, both early and late consumers receive a fraction of CE. Essentially, the government insures current deposits rather than promised payments. While admittedly quite crude, this configuration of policy choices and market conditions matches the description of the savings and loan industry in the 1980s provided by White (1991). Consider first the extent of deposit insurance coverage in the United States. Note that partial insurance is ostensibly a component of U.S. policy through limits on coverage. However, it is well understood that in a large number of cases, such as Continental Illinois in 1984, the U.S. government did provide deposit insurance to individuals with accounts in excess of the 20 White (1991) admits that the regulators had a very difficult job in this new environment and that they even suffered from some very bad luck. For example, a key Texas office was moved at just the
  • 48. wrong time-disrupting the work of regulators just when their oversight was needed the most. 21 In related research, Grossman (1992) studies the risk-taking behavior of insured and uninsured thrift institutions in Milwaukee and Chicago during the 1930s. He finds evidence of moral hazard in that after a few years of deposit insurance coverage, thrifts would move toward holding riskier portfolios. He also finds that the level of regulatory oversight influenced the degree of risk taking. Federally insured thrifts were the most heavily regulated and took on less risk than their state- chartered counterparts. And the stricter regulation in Wisconsin led thrifts in that state to build less risky portfolios than those of state-chartered thrifts in Illinois, where the regulations were less stringent. 22 Mechanisms such as this, where deflation leads to incentive problems, are often discussed in the literature on financial frictions. 23 By assumption, the deposit insurance covers the same fraction of early and late consumption. Hence, more sophisticated policies that might prevent runs without creating a moral hazard problem by insuring early consumption only are not considered. 66 This content downloaded from 141.161.91.14 on Sat, 30 Mar 2019 02:57:00 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
  • 49. DEPOSIT INSURANCE AND INCENTIVES $100,000 cap.24 Diamond and Dybvig (1986) suggest that since the government did not credibly commit ex ante to pay off all depositors (which might have protected the bank from the capital flight it experienced) but then covered those losses ex post, "they incurred the expense of deposit insurance without the benefits" (p. 64). With regard to capital requirements, the losses suffered by many S&Ls had ef- fectively reduced their capital to levels so low that shareholders had relatively little to lose from making high-risk investments. With these investments, they were es- sentially gambling with taxpayers' money. Hence it is of interest to determine the model's predictions under this scenario, to see if we have a structure that can explain what actually happened. There is an obvious concern associated with this characterization of deposit in- surance: taking a as given, an intermediary has the incentive to make outrageous promises to depositors, given that the government is insuring these offers. While the removal of Regulation Q certainly gave the intermediaries more latitude, some constraint on the choice of 6 = (CE, CL) must be imposed. In our analysis, we assume that the government will provide insurance iff the terms of 3
  • 50. solve the contracting problem given the level of deposit insurance and under the presumption that the bank will not invest in the risky illiquid technology. Given that the environment is public information, there is no reason for the government to insure contracts that are only reasonable if the bank commits moral hazard and invests in risky projects. As a consequence, the bank is unable to pass along gains from excessive risk taking to depositors.25 To make the role of monitoring clear, we make use of (4) and assume that there is effectively only a single agent who can either monitor the bank or not. Since the cost of monitoring has been assumed to take the form of a utility loss, the contracting problems specified above do not change as we vary the cost of monitoring. Further, following Proposition 1, the bank chooses to invest funds in either the risky illiquid investment project or the riskless illiquid investment project. 24 The Federal Deposit Insurance Company employs two strategies to deal with failed institutions: deposit payoff and deposit assumption. In the former case, depositors simply receive their funds and the bank is closed. In the latter case, the bank is taken over by another institution and FDIC funds are used to compensate the acquiring bank. In this case, large and small depositors are protected. Since a large fraction of the resolution of bank failures has
  • 51. been through deposit assumption, large depositors have, in effect, received insurance. The FDIC Annual Report provides a more complete explanation and data on the frequency of use of these policies. We are grateful to Warren Weber and Art Rolnick for discussions of this point. 25 One could add an element of unobservable side payments from the bank to depositors into the model to allow the sharing of these gains. As discussed below, this would certainly influence the characterization of the critical value of deposit insurance in Proposition 2 but not change the results qualitatively. An alternative approach that would permit some of the gains from this risk taking to be passed on to depositors would allow the bank to offer depositors contracts that it would have the resources to fully honor only if the risky investment was successful. That is, suppose regulators could not observe v and believed the bank's claim that v = 1. In this case with full deposit insurance the bank can-indeed competition will force it to-provide more generous deposit contracts knowing that the deposit insurer will certainly be needed if the risky project fails. So again we have the depositors and shareholders both wanting to invest in the risky, inefficient project. 67 This content downloaded from 141.161.91.14 on Sat, 30 Mar 2019 02:57:00 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
  • 52. COOPER AND ROSS This discrete choice highlights the moral hazard problem for the bank and its depositors. Finally, we assume that q is sufficiently small so that the contract with runs dominates the runs-preventing contract in the absence of deposit insurance. Hence, when we characterize the optimal contract in the presence of deposit insurance, the assumption that q is small implies that the private sector will not adopt runs- preventing contracts. We comment below on the robustness of our results to the alternative assumption that q is large enough to warrant the adoption of runs- preventing contracts, at least for some levels of deposit insurance. With complete deposit insurance (c = 1), the intermediary will prefer to invest in the risky illiquid technology and depositors will not care since, in effect, they are gambling with other agents' money. At the other extreme of no deposit insurance (a = 0), there is no moral hazard problem if monitoring costs are low enough so that depositors monitor the intermediary and thus force the inter- mediary to invest in the riskless illiquid technique. From this, it is not surprising that there exists a critical level of deposit insurance, denoted a', at which depositors are indifferent between investment in the risky and
  • 53. riskless ventures. This leads to the following characterization of the optimal level of deposit insurance, c*. PROPOSITION 2. The optimal level of deposit insurance will be at one of two levels, Ca* E {a', 1}. PROOF. To understand the possibility of a* = o', consider first the design of the best contract allowing for runs in the presence of deposit insurance assuming that the intermediary uses the riskless illiquid technique. This is (3) modified to include deposit insurance, i.e., (8) max(1 - q)[7U(cE) + (1 - T)U(CL)] + q U(CE) ( + U(OCCE) ( 1 CE,CL CE CE s.t. (1 - n)cL = R(1 - 71CE) Let b(c) = (cE(x), cL(a)) denote the solution to this contracting problem. Now consider the optimal contract allowing for runs in the presence of deposit insurance assuming that the intermediary uses the risky illiquid technique. This is clearly preferred by the intermediary, given that its shareholders benefit when the risky project succeeds and bear no risk if it fails. Put differently, with no capital requirement, the bank will have an incentive to invest in the risky technique.
  • 54. Will the depositors monitor? Given 65(a) and the assumption of a single monitor, (4) becomes (9) (1 - 7)(1 - v)(1 - q)[U(cL(x)) - U(0c(cL(a)))] > r Let a' be the level of deposit insurance such that (9) holds as an equality. We assume that r is small enough so that monitoring will occur at a = 0 but not for a near 1. So by continuity of U(.) and hence continuity of the solution to (8), a' e (0, 1). In sum, if the government sets the level of deposit insurance at a', it would anticipate 68 This content downloaded from 141.161.91.14 on Sat, 30 Mar 2019 02:57:00 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms DEPOSIT INSURANCE AND INCENTIVES that the optimal contract would solve (8) and the depositor would be indifferent between monitoring and not monitoring. At a = 1, there will be no bank runs and no monitoring. Hence, investment will be in the risky illiquid investment. It is straightforward to see that only two values of deposit insurance are relevant.
  • 55. For values of a c [0, c'], there is no moral hazard as the bank is always monitored. Starting at a 0, increases in a would just change the level of insurance given to depositors. As the best contract does not eliminate runs, this insurance may have social value. For values of a c (c', 1), there is a moral hazard problem but there are no additional incentive problems created by increasing the level of deposit insur- ance from o' toward 1. Hence, it is sufficient to compare social welfare at c' with that at 1. U Intuitively, the reduction of the optimal deposit insurance rate to the two possible outcomes reflects the trade-off between insurance and moral hazard. For c < a', consumers monitor and prevent the risky venture. At a = a', the incentives change and for a > c', depositors are unwilling to monitor and thus intermediaries choose risky illiquid investments. Thus, a key aspect of the proof concerns the existence of a'. Thus, with inadequate capital requirements, the government is forced to choose between the insurance gains from deposit insurance and its adverse incentive effects. In our model, this trade-off is reflected in the choice between a* = 1 and a* = c'. By continuity, if q is sufficiently close to zero so that the prospect of runs is infinitesimal, then the best policy is to adopt partial deposit insurance and thus avoid bank moral hazard problems. Alternatively, if the moral hazard problem is itself small, say
  • 56. because vi is near 1, then it is best to offer full deposit insurance. Regardless of whether deposit insurance is full or partial, it is important to note that the first-best outcome is not achieved. In the case of partial deposit insurance, depositors will monitor the bank but they face either strategic uncertainty or the inefficiencies created by a runs-preventing contract. Full deposit insurance clearly creates an incentive problem since the interests of the bank and its depositors are aligned. Thus, even if monitoring costs are 0, the first-best is not obtained. We consider the robustness of these results with respect to two important assump- tions. First, if monitoring was the outcome of the interaction of multiple agents rather than just one, then the conditions for monitoring would not be given by (4) and the optimal action by the government would change. We show elsewhere that the critical value of a characterized in Proposition 2 is relevant for the case of multiple depositors. In particular, if a > ', then the Nash equilibrium is for no depositor to monitor. That is, if no other depositor monitors, then the remaining agent uses (4) to determine whether or not monitoring is desirable so that c' is again the critical level of insurance. For a < a', the symmetric Nash equilibrium will entail monitoring and the probability that any individual agent monitors will increase as a falls.26 Second, suppose that q was large enough so that, in the absence
  • 57. of deposit insurance, banks would have elected to offer runs-preventing contracts. In such a 26 These results are contained in an earlier version of this article, available from the authors upon request. 69 This content downloaded from 141.161.91.14 on Sat, 30 Mar 2019 02:57:00 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms COOPER AND ROSS case, the provision of partial deposit insurance can have the perverse effect of increasing the probability of runs. The insurance can make it optimal to abandon the runs-preventing contract and if the insurance is not complete runs can still happen. Thus, while with zero monitoring costs the best runs- preventing contract will involve neither runs nor moral hazard, adding partial deposit insurance can lead to both. 5. CONCLUSIONS The goal of this article has been to extend the Diamond-Dybvig framework to understand the implications of runs and moral hazard for the evaluation of the costs
  • 58. and benefits of deposit insurance. In our analysis, as in that of Diamond-Dybvig, there is a clear benefit to the provision of deposit insurance as it prevents runs. The costs modeled here are associated with a reduction in the incentives for depositors to monitor, giving rise to riskier investments by intermediaries. From the perspective of our model, the first-best allocation is achievable with a combination of policies. Deposit insurance is needed to avoid bank runs. Capital requirements are needed to overcome the adverse incentive problems associated with the provision of deposit insurance. The article has demonstrated that one potential consequence of the combination of an inadequate capital requirement, say due to regulatory failure, with a generous deposit insurance fund is the type of banking instability observed in the U.S. during the 1980s. We therefore believe that our article contributes to an understanding of what happened to many of the failed S&Ls. This work leaves a number of interesting avenues for future research. For ex- ample, we do not explicitly consider here the implications of risk-based deposit insurance plans. The 1991 FDIC Improvement Act mandated a move toward risk- based premia in the United States and a similar program appears to be coming to
  • 59. deposit insurance in Canada. While it might appear that such policies would solve the runs problem without introducing moral hazard, much depends on the timing of moves. If bank owners can adjust their portfolios after premia have been paid, then the problems we analyze here may remain. The premia, once paid, become a sunk cost that will not influence future investment behavior. Of course, in a multiperiod environment, "punishments" can be administered in the future in the form of higher premia, but in the case of banks with depleted capital bases, and therefore nothing much to lose, the punishment might come too late.27 While the model developed here does present simple conditions to achieve the first-best outcome, potential limitations of this solution arise from the presence of moral hazard between bank owners and managers and difficulties in raising 27 This point is also made by Freixas and Rochet (1997, p. 270). Chan et al. (1992) demonstrate the impossibility of fairly priced deposit insurance in a model with asymmetric information and incentive compatibility constraints. Dewatripont and Tirole (1994) argue that "it is extremely difficult to devise proper risk-based premiums, especially if those are to be determined in a transparent, nondiscretionary manner" (pp. 60-61). They characterize the American approach with premiums ranging from 23 to 31 cents per $100 of deposits as "very timid."
  • 60. 70 This content downloaded from 141.161.91.14 on Sat, 30 Mar 2019 02:57:00 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms DEPOSIT INSURANCE AND INCENTIVES sufficient equity capital. Further, the equity capital requirement must be adjusted in response to changes in the economic environment. These adjustments and the continued monitoring of compliance with this requirement might be costly. We leave the question of the second-best policies in this environment for future research. REFERENCES ALONSO, I., "On Avoiding Bank Runs," Journal of Monetary Economics 37 (1996), 73-87. BENTAL, B., Z. ECKSTEIN, AND D. PELED, "Competitive Banking with Fractional Reserves and Regulations," working paper no. 10-90, Foerder Institute for Economic Research, Tel Aviv University, April 1990. BESANKO, D., AND G. KANATAS, "Credit Market Equilibrium with Bank Monitoring and Moral Hazard," Review of Financial Studies 6 (1993), 213-32.
  • 61. CALOMIRIS, C., AND C. KAHN, "The Role of Demandable Debt in Structuring Optimal Banking Arrangements," American Economic Review 81 (1991), 497- 513. CHAN, Y., S. GREENBAUM, AND A. THAKOR, "Is Fairly Priced Deposit Insurance Possible?," Journal of Finance 47 (1992), 227-45. COOPER, R., AND T. W. Ross, "Bank Runs: Liquidity and Incentives," NBER Working Paper #3921, November 1991. AND , "Bank Runs: Liquidity Costs and Investment Distortions," Journal of Monetary Economics 41 (1998), 27-38. DEWATRIPONT, M., AND J. TIROLE, The Prudential Regulation of Banks (Cambridge, MA: MIT Press, 1994). DIAMOND, D., AND P. DYBVIG, "Bank Runs, Deposit Insurance and Liquidity," Journal of Political Economy 91 (1983), 401-19. AND , "Banking Theory, Deposit Insurance and Bank Regulation," Journal of Business 59 (1986), 55-68. FELDSTEIN, M., "The Risks of Economic Crisis: Introduction," in M. Feldstein, ed., The Risks of Economic Crisis (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1991). FREEMAN, S., "Banking as the Provision of Liquidity," Journal of Business 61 (1988), 45-64. FREIXAS, X., AND J.-C. ROCHET, Microeconomics of
  • 62. Banking (Cambridge, MA: MIT Press, 1997). GIAMMARINO, R., T. LEWIS, AND D. SAPPINGTON, "An Incentive Approach to Banking Regu- lation," Journal of Finance 48 (1993), 1523-42. GROSSMAN, R. S., "Deposit Insurance, Regulation, and Moral Hazard in the Thrift Industry: Evi- dence from the 1930s," American Economic Review 82 (1992), 800-21. HOLMSTROM, B., AND J. TIROLE, "Financial Intermediation, Loanable Funds and the Real Sec- tor," mimeo, IDEI, Toulouse University, 1993. JACKLIN, C., "Demand Deposits, Trading Restrictions and Risk Sharing," in E. Prescott and N. Wallace, eds., Contractual Arrangements for Intertemporal Trade, Minnesota Studies in Macroeconomics, Vol. I (Minneapolis: University of Minnesota Press, 1987). KORMENDI, R., V. BERNARD, S. C. PIRRONG, AND E. SNYDER, Crisis Resolution in the Thrift Industry (Boston: Kluwer Academic Publishers, 1989). KUPIEC, P., AND J. O'BRIEN, "Deposit Insurance, Bank Incentives, and the Design of Regulatory Policy," mimeo, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, December 1997. MATUTES, C., AND X. VIVES, "Competition for Deposits, Fragility and Insurance," Journal of Financial Intermediation 5 (1996), 184-216.
  • 63. PECK, J., AND K. SHELL, "Bank Portfolio Restrictions and Equilibrium Bank Runs," mimeo, Ohio State University, 1999. SMITH, B., AND R. WHITE, "The Deposit Insurance System in Canada: Problems and Proposals for Change," Canadian Public Policy 14 (1988), 331-46. 71 This content downloaded from 141.161.91.14 on Sat, 30 Mar 2019 02:57:00 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms 72 COOPER AND ROSS WALLACE, N., "Another Attempt to Explain an Illiquid Banking System: The Diamond-Dybvig Model with Sequential Service Taken Seriously," Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Quarterly Review 12 (1988), 3-16. WHITE, L., The S&L Debacle: Public Policy Lessons for Bank and Thrift Regulation (New York: Oxford University Press, 1991). This content downloaded from 141.161.91.14 on Sat, 30 Mar 2019 02:57:00 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms Project can be of any length you like, from a few pages to 20 (although I doubt any of you will have 20 pages to write). I do NOT want you to write random stuff just to fill the pages, I
  • 64. want to read essential information. The logic to follow is similar to what you see when you read the papers we have studied: abstract (very short), introduction (where you say what your question is and why it is interesting, and how you will study it) and then the body of the paper. Finally a conclusion that can be again very short and usually it is just saying the same things as the abstract. If you do not have a mathematical model that’s also ok, although I would encourage you to think through the frameworks we have seen carefully and you might find useful material.