SlideShare a Scribd company logo
1 of 83
261
Megaregion Planning
and High-Speed Rail
Petra Todorovich
c h a p t e r 2 4
?
On April 16, 2009, President Obama stood before an audience at
the Eisenhower
Executive Office Building and made an announcement that
signaled a new era of
passenger rail in the United States. Months before, the
American Recovery and
Reinvestment Act (ARRA) had provided $8 billion for a new
program at the
Federal Railroad Administration (FRA) to issue competitive
grants to states to
make capital investments in high-speed and conventional
passenger rail. Little did
the president know that providing the single largest boost for
intercity rail plan-
ning in this country in a generation had also motivated a sudden
and giant leap for-
ward in planning and governing megaregions. Luckily, regional
planners had been
studying emerging megaregions for the previous five years, in
affiliation with the
New York–based Regional Plan Association’s (RPA) America
2050 program. Again
and again, the planners had identified high-speed rail as the key
transportation
investment to serve megaregion economies. But high-speed rail
was a distant
dream. That all changed with the passage of ARRA at the nadir
of the Great
Recession. Now a federal program exists to support high-speed
rail planning
and implementation. Making that program a success will largely
depend on the
ability of multiple actors at the local, regional, state, and
binational levels to come
together as megaregions to coordinate and leverage federal rail
investments.
Revisiting Megalopolis: RPA Resurrects
the Megaregion Idea
As if planning for the Tri-State New York metropolitan region
was not sufficiently
complicated, in 2005 the Regional Plan Association launched a
national program
called America 2050 that focused on the emergence of a new
urban scale: the
megaregion. This was not actually a new concept for RPA. In
1967 a volume of the
Second Regional Plan documented the emergence of “The
Atlantic Urban Region,”
an urban chain stretching 460 miles from Maine to Virginia
(Regional Plan
C
o
p
y
r
i
g
h
t
2
0
1
1
.
R
u
t
g
e
r
s
U
n
i
v
e
r
s
i
t
y
P
r
e
s
s
.
A
l
l
r
i
g
h
t
s
r
e
s
e
r
v
e
d
.
M
a
y
n
o
t
b
e
r
e
p
r
o
d
u
c
e
d
i
n
a
n
y
f
o
r
m
w
i
t
h
o
u
t
p
e
r
m
i
s
s
i
o
n
f
r
o
m
t
h
e
p
u
b
l
i
s
h
e
r
,
e
x
c
e
p
t
f
a
i
r
u
s
e
s
p
e
r
m
i
t
t
e
d
u
n
d
e
r
U
.
S
.
o
r
a
p
p
l
i
c
a
b
l
e
c
o
p
y
r
i
g
h
t
l
a
w
.
EBSCO Publishing : eBook Academic Collection (EBSCOhost)
- printed on 5/8/2020 3:56 AM via SAN JOSE STATE UNIV
AN: 435124 ; Montgomery, Carleton.; Regional Planning for a
Sustainable America : How Creative Programs Are Promoting
Prosperity and Saving the Environment
Account: s7380033.main.cmmc
Association 1967). Earlier that decade, French geographer Jean
Gottmann had
coined the term “Megalopolis” to describe the same region in
his 1961 book,
Megalopolis: The Urbanized Northeastern Seaboard of the
United States (Gottmann
1961). The Northeast’s more or less continuous urbanization
from the northern
suburbs of Boston to the southern suburbs of Washington, D.C.,
had attracted the
attention of Gottmann and RPA. But in 1967 RPA observed that
while this chain of
settlements containing 42 million people surely derived some
benefit from their
mutual proximity, the larger form of the Atlantic Urban Region
was still composed
of more or less independent metropolitan regions.
By 2005, when RPA revisited that larger form, the autonomy of
the Northeast’s
metropolitan regions was starting to wane. Rapid, low-density
sprawl was erasing
the formerly distinct boundaries between the New York and
Philadelphia metro-
politan regions, and between Philadelphia and Wilmington. The
term “extreme
commutes” had been coined by the U.S. Census to describe road
warriors traveling
more than ninety minutes each way to their jobs, with many of
them located in the
Northeast. And intercity business travel within the Northeast
was also growing.
The four most congested airports in the country were located in
New York City,
Newark, and Philadelphia. With 251 daily flights taking place
among the
Northeast’s major airports, and 40 percent of Amtrak’s rail
ridership taking place
on the Northeast Corridor, a Northeast Megaregion was moving
from a spatial
construct to reality (RPA 2007).
But at the dawn of the twenty-first century, the forces making
the Northeast
Megaregion a more cohesive and integrated megaregion were
also threatening its
demise. Growing congestion in its roads, rail network, and
airports; rising house
costs; loss of open space; and threats to clean drinking water all
contributed to
imperil the Northeast’s future as an economic competitor and
healthy and pleas-
ant place to live. In other words, the Northeast was (and is)
heading toward the
dystopian vision of Megalopolis—a region of continuous sprawl
with infrastruc-
ture systems that are too crowded and too deteriorated to
function efficiently,
a high cost of living, and a natural environment that has
suffered the impacts of
an aggressive human footprint. As Regional Plan Association’s
president, Robert
Yaro, frequently remarks, “The Northeast has all the
disadvantages of being the
most expensive, densely populated, and congested region in the
country—and
none of the advantages.” The subtext of this statement is that
we need to flip the
equation around and capture the benefits of having the most
population density,
the most expansive rail transit network, and the largest
concentration of skilled
workers in the nation. To do so, RPA set out to understand the
larger phenomenon
of megaregions and how they were playing out around the
country.
Scaling Up: America’s Emerging Megaregions
In 2004 Robert Yaro, Armando Carbonell, and Jonathan Barnett
led a graduate
planning studio at the University of Pennsylvania called Plan
for America. The Plan
for America studio traveled to Europe on spring break to meet
with Sir Peter Hall at
s o c i e t y , e c o n o m i c s a n d p l a n n i n g262
EBSCOhost - printed on 5/8/2020 3:56 AM via SAN JOSE
STATE UNIV. All use subject to https://www.ebsco.com/terms-
of-use
University College London, where students and professors alike
were inspired by
the European Spatial Development Perspective (ESDP), a 1999
policy statement on
balanced growth in the European territory. The imaginative
spatial planners behind
the ESDP had identified large urban agglomerations in Central
Europe like the
Pentagon and the Blue Banana (Faludi 2002). Also called
“global integration zones,”
these networked cities and regions in the EU were supported by
open border
policies among EU member states and strengthened by EU
investments in the
Trans-European Network and high-speed passenger rail.
Adopting a similar spatial
perspective on urban networks in America, the Penn students
identified a series of
possible “supercities,” which were later redefined by RPA as
megaregions.
RPA launched its America 2050 program after the Penn students
issued their
final report in spring 2004. The RPA prospectus on America
2050 outlined the case
for adopting a megaregion perspective and national plan (RPA
2006). Generally, it
argued that five major trends shaping the United States
demanded a national plan-
ning and infrastructure strategy for accommodating future
growth. They included
the following:
• America’s rapid population growth, about 130 million
additional people by 2050
• Overburdened and deteriorating infrastructure systems
• The urgent need to mitigate climate change and reduce our
dependence on
fossil fuels and oil imports
• Growing social and economic disparities within and between
regions
• And the emergence of a new urban form: megaregions
Megaregions are networks of proximate metropolitan regions,
connected
by transportation systems, natural systems, settlement patterns,
and linked
economies. Eleven emerging U.S. megaregions capture over 70
percent of the
nation’s population and jobs (see fig. 24.1). They present a new
scale at which to
plan and coordinate large infrastructure and natural systems—a
scale at which
there are few examples of governance models, let alone
institutions capable of
planning or financing complex systems like high-speed rail.
Given this vacuum,
America 2050 set out to address a planning void at two different
scales: federal,
where leadership would surely be required to help plan, finance,
and facilitate
partnerships needed to meet the challenges described here; and
the megaregion,
by conducting research, building coalitions, and identifying best
practices for
megaregion planning and coordination.
The first several years of the America 2050 program were spent
building a base
of research to underpin our understanding of megaregions and
verify that this
urban form was present outside the Northeast. All of the
research that America
2050 assembled is located permanently on the America 2050
website in its research
section. During this time, RPA began to think about
megaregions as organized
around specific relationships that present themselves at the
larger scale—such as
water resources in the Great Lakes Megaregion, intercity rail in
the Northeast
Corridor, a common coastline and vulnerability to natural and
man-made
disasters in the Gulf Coast, seaport and goods movement issues
in southern
f i n d i n g a c a t a l y s t i n h i g h - s p e e d r a i l 263
EBSCOhost - printed on 5/8/2020 3:56 AM via SAN JOSE
STATE UNIV. All use subject to https://www.ebsco.com/terms-
of-use
F
ig
u
re
2
4.
1.
E
m
er
gi
n
g
M
eg
ar
eg
io
n
s
o
f
th
e
U
n
it
ed
S
ta
te
s
EBSCOhost - printed on 5/8/2020 3:56 AM via SAN JOSE
STATE UNIV. All use subject to https://www.ebsco.com/terms-
of-use
California, and urban sprawl in northern California.
Recognizing these critical
relationships was the key to unlocking interest by regional
stakeholders in cooper-
ating with each other. “You’re in a megaregion; do something
about it” was not a
compelling opening line. However, they found that “working
with your neighbors
is critical to solving fill-in-the-blank” elicited much more
interest.
From 2005 to 2008, megaregion studies were conducted in eight
megaregions,
mostly at or in partnership with graduate planning schools,
including University of
Pennsylvania, Georgia Tech, Portland State University, Arizona
State University,
University of Michigan, and University of Texas at Austin. In
addition, several
councils of governments in California (Sacramento Area
Council of Governments,
San Diego Association of Governments, and Kern County)
published a study of
the Southwest Megaregion, which led to their continued
cooperation on goods
movement and airport planning. In Florida, the South Florida
Regional Planning
Council prepared a study of the Florida Megaregion and
convened a conference
around it in 2006. In northern California, the independent
planning and civic
organization SPUR published a study of the Northern California
Megaregion,
stretching from the Bay Area to Sacramento. Following the
SPUR study, trans-
portation officials from across the megaregion came together to
submit a joint
application for a northern California freight program that was
successful in secur-
ing $840 million from the California Transportation
Commission, an achievement
they regarded as a “coup” (Nelson 2008).
Rail Advocacy in the Northeast Corridor
Back in the Northeast Megaregion, RPA helped revive a
coalition of business groups
that had previously advocated for Amtrak funding to form the
Business Alliance for
Northeast Mobility. With a reinvigorated membership of about
thirty chambers of
commerce and civic organizations from Maine to Virginia, the
Business Alliance
began lobbying Congress in 2006 for increased rail funding to
bring Amtrak’s
Northeast Rail Corridor to a state of good repair. The Business
Alliance focused on
turning one of the key disadvantages of the Northeast’s
geography—fragmented
governance among twelve states—into a political advantage—
twenty-four U.S.
senators and dozens more U.S. representatives. The Business
Alliance held several
rail advocacy events at the U.S. Capitol and at Union Station in
Washington, D.C.,
in 2007–2008 with members of the Northeast Delegation. The
strategy seemed to
work. In 2008, after previous unsuccessful attempts, Congress
passed the Passenger
Rail Investment Improvement Act, which authorized
approximately $13 billion in
funding for Amtrak over five years and set up a new High Speed
Intercity Passenger
Rail program at the Federal Railroad Administration that
provided competitive
grants to states to invest in capital improvements for passenger
rail. This new
program was put to use immediately, by serving as the
legislative vehicle for the
$8 billion appropriation of high-speed rail funding in ARRA.
The subsequent year,
federal appropriators reaffirmed their commitment to the high-
speed rail program
with another $2.5 billion for the high-speed program.
f i n d i n g a c a t a l y s t i n h i g h - s p e e d r a i l 265
EBSCOhost - printed on 5/8/2020 3:56 AM via SAN JOSE
STATE UNIV. All use subject to https://www.ebsco.com/terms-
of-use
With painful irony, a relatively small share of the money made
its way to the
Northeast Corridor. The Business Alliance had gambled on
advocating for
increased national rail funding, because about half of Amtrak’s
annual capital
investments are typically made in the Northeast Corridor,
Amtrak’s largest rail
infrastructure asset. And, indeed, approximately $706 million
included in ARRA
for Amtrak came to the Northeast Corridor in 2009, along with
additional funding
in the 2010 annual appropriation (Federal Railroad
Administration 2010). But little
of the $8 billion in high-speed rail grants came to the Northeast
Corridor, for two
frustratingly technical reasons. None of Amtrak’s Northeast
Corridor projects
could be completed in two years—a statutory requirement of the
stimulus bill—
and the Northeast Corridor states had recently initiated a master
planning process
for 2030, which had triggered the need for a new, corridor-wide
environmental
impact statement (EIS). All of the high-speed rail grants from
the stimulus bill
required a completed EIS, and the Northeast Corridor’s had yet
to begin and
would certainly take a minimum of two years. So after playing a
role in securing
rail funding for the entire country, the Northeast Corridor sat on
the sidelines as
the largest passenger rail grants in decades were doled out in
California, Florida,
the Midwest, and other regions.
On the bright side, being passed over seems to have acted as a
wake-up call
to transportation officials in the Northeast states, who have
reemerged with
greater motivation to better coordinate in the future for federal
funding. In
June 2010, eleven Northeast states submitted an application to
the FRA for $18.8
million in planning funds to conduct a comprehensive planning
study for the
Northeast Corridor, building on the master plan. The new
planning study would
allow Northeast states to break out individual capital projects
on the corridor
with independent utility that could be funded through the
federal high-speed rail
program and complete the required EIS for the corridor for a
doubling of ridership
by 2030. Of most interest to this author, the planning study and
EIS would also
consider a true high-speed rail option of building two new
dedicated tracks along
the Northeast Corridor for high-speed trains, significantly
increasing capacity and
reducing trip times on the corridor—and competing with the
other world-class
high-speed rail systems being planned in California and Florida.
Such an outcome
could be the key to realizing the promise of an integrated
Northeast Megaregion
economy and act as the ultimate test for megaregion
cooperation.
Megaregions and High-Speed Rail
High-speed rail is not just a test for megaregion coordination; it
also promises
great reward. In fact, it is likely that only with the fast and
convenient ground
connections provided by high-speed rail can megaregions
realize the productivity
benefits of their metropolitan economies acting as integrated
units. This is the
difference between the Northeast Megaregion’s dystopian future
and the desired
path. High-speed rail could act as the main intercity
transportation spine for an
expanded megaregion-scale rail transit network, enhanced with
transit oriented
s o c i e t y , e c o n o m i c s a n d p l a n n i n g266
EBSCOhost - printed on 5/8/2020 3:56 AM via SAN JOSE
STATE UNIV. All use subject to https://www.ebsco.com/terms-
of-use
development. A Northeast megaregion (and other megaregions)
linked by high-
speed rail could potentially realize the following benefits:
• Increased productivity for service-based businesses gained by
time savings
and increased mobility. Faster, more frequent, and reliable
connections that
enable business trips among the specialized economies of the
Northeast
(i.e., education and health services in Boston; financial services
and media in
New York; government and professional services in
Washington) can foster
greater productivity for the megaregion as a whole.
• Expanding the scope of labor markets accessed by major
employment centers.
Faster rail connections between employment hubs and adjacent,
smaller cities
and residential areas can deepen labor markets, giving
employers access to
more workers and providing workers with more and cheaper
housing options
(Martin Prosperity Insight 2010).
• Bringing smaller and underperforming cities within two-hour
commuting
distance of major employment hubs (like Boston, New York,
and
Washington) can potentially benefit cities like Hartford,
Worcester, and
Philadelphia, which have been losing jobs steadily in recent
decades. This
could also take pressure off the housing market in larger cities,
if workers
can work in New York and live in Philadelphia, for example
(Regional Plan
Association 2007).
• Focusing development and real estate opportunities around
stations.
Rail passenger stations provide focal points for transportation-
oriented
development, such as new office, retail, institutional, and
residential
development. Focusing development around transportation hubs
can reduce
the need to drive, enliven and activate communities, and
promote energy
savings through transportation and building related efficiencies.
Regional planning must recognize and capitalize on the self-
interest of local
actors that make up a region in order to be successful.
Megaregion planning is no
different in its need to tap into the mutual self-interest of
component metropolitan
actors. Yet megaregion planning is even more difficult than
regional planning
because the megaregion scale is less connected to individuals’
daily experiences
than the metropolitan region. In light of these challenges,
America 2050 has found
that megaregion cooperation must be motivated by the promise
of clear and
tangible rewards to be gained by megaregion cooperation. Such
rewards, in the
form of federal high-speed rail planning grants, have recently
brought megaregions
together to develop corridor-wide rail plans and explore
governance models
for finance, construction, and rail service operations. These
regions, particularly
those that span multiple states and international boundaries,
will need to
establish formal partnerships to manage major procedures like
procurement and
financing. The greater promise of high-speed rail—increased
productivity, access
to larger job markets, promoting sustainable land development,
and revitalizing
cities—will require a broader regional planning perspective at
the megaregion
scale. In this way, high speed is providing a laboratory for
megaregion planning.
f i n d i n g a c a t a l y s t i n h i g h - s p e e d r a i l 267
EBSCOhost - printed on 5/8/2020 3:56 AM via SAN JOSE
STATE UNIV. All use subject to https://www.ebsco.com/terms-
of-use
WPC 480.
Week 8
1
For next week…
Complete Case Paper #3 on Aldi
Due at our next class March 19th
Focused on Cost Leadership and Differentiation Strategies.
NO Blue Ocean!
NO Business Models
Focus on Chapter
(After tonight – it’s Spring Break)
2
Generic Business Strategies
Differentiation
Seeks to create higher value than competitors
Offers products or services with unique features
Keeps the firm’s cost structure as low as possible
Charges higher prices
Cost Leadership
Seeks to create similar value as competitors
Products or services delivered at lower cost
Charges lower prices
Business-level Strategies
Cost leadership
Sources of keeping costs down and prices low
Cost of input factors (supplier power matters here)
Economies of scale
Employing specialized systems and equipment
Minimum efficient scale – increases in volume do not lead to
further cost reductions
Implies large market share almost always to get the best
economies of scale
8
Cost leadership:
It takes time to reduce costs
Learning Curve Effects – price drops (and quality increases) as
volume increases over time
Versus Economy of Scales: Economy of Scales are a specific
points in time versus accumulation over time
Differences in Complexity: Depending on product/service EoS
may have stronger impacts than learning curves
Experience Curve Effects – price drops (and quality increases)
with changes in technology of production
Process Innovation: changes in technology allow increased
efficiency with same output volume.
Technology can be changes in methods or machinery
9
Attributes of the Product/Service offering
Relationships between company and consumers
Linkages within or between firms
Differentiation Strategy
Blue Ocean Strategy
Value Innovation: Aligning consumer utility, price and cost for
maximizing value to company and consumer – product
differentiation and low cost.
8
Blue Ocean Strategy
Strategy Canvas: Captures current state of the known market
place and action framework to explore alternatives.
9
Blue Ocean Strategy
4 Action Framework: To assist in creating a new value curve
the 4 Action Framework helps evaluate the tradeoffs between
differentiation and cost.
10
Blue Ocean Strategy
11
Blue Ocean Shift
12
Activity
In your group, identify a company who has a Blue Ocean
strategy
Identify that BO company’s competitors or industry
Identify the factors that consumers use to make decisions about
their purchases with this company.
What factors were raised/created by the BO company or
eliminated/decreased?
13
Risks of Blue Ocean
Finding the right blue ocean – easy to say but hard to
find/create
Arriving too early and/or Being too new, too different – are
consumers ready?
Strategy Execution – Right leaders?
Strategic Clarity and Mindset – ready for the challenges from
top to bottom
Trust and Patience
How defensible is your new ocean?
14
Blue Ocean vs. Yoda
15
Tradeoffs
Maintain a focus on the consumer
Who won’t buy the products/services, or which
potentially profitable consumers are ignored or
avoided?
Mutually exclusive choices to commit resources
Tradeoffs give something up – they “hurt”
Resource commitments other firms cannot easily match
Questions for you as an analyst
Sufficient consistency in tradeoffs over time?
Inconsistency creates a “stuck in the middle” situation where
the firm is not great at any one thing
Strategic discipline to avoid being “stuck in the middle”
No firm starts wanting to be stuck in the middle
Discipline over time required to be true to tradeoffs
How do these threaten discipline in tradeoffs?
Customers
Employees
Management
Shareholders
Technology
The Conundrum
18
Drew Houston, Founder of DropBox
Attributes of the Product/Service offering
Features, Complexity/Simplicity, Location
Relationships between company and consumers
Customization, Marketing, Brand, Services
Linkages within or between firms
Enhancing connections to other parts of a business or to another
business
Complement – consuming in tandem
Networks
Differentiation Strategy
2018 US
best sellers by volume
1. Ford F Series 909K
2. Chevy Silverado 586K
3. Ram Pickup 537K
4. Toyota RAV4 427K
5. Nissan Rogue 412K
How are they differentiated?
6. Honda CR-V 379K
7. Toyota Camry 343K
8. Chevy Equinox 333K
https://www.automobilemag.com/news/year-auto-sales-facts-
figures-bestsellers-2018/
https://www.caranddriver.com/news/g25558401/best-selling-
cars-suv-trucks-2018/?slide=25
20
Problem of sustaining:
What won’t we do?
US$211,000 Lamborghini Urus
US$33,000 Nissan Rogue Sport
US$130,000 Porsche Cayenne
US$171,000 Maserati Levante
US$40,000 Volkswagen Tiguan
US$46,000 Mazda CX-9
Activity
Breaking into groups
Consider ASU and its competitors
How is ASU Differentiated?
How is W. P. Carey Differentiated?
What factors would you highlight for each of the above?
22
Managerial levers to differentiate a firm strategically
Clear goal for strategy (the constant checklist)
Who?
What will we satisfy?
Why do we want to do this?
How we will do this?
Levers to differentiate
Product features (blurs w/marketing)
Customer service (blurs w/operations here)
Complements (blurs w/industry boundaries AND competitors)
Example: Disney World, Sea World, Universal Studios and
Orlando air flights
Networks effects, or why not to buy a Fiat in the U.S.
What is meaningful about being a differentiator?
How does this strategy motivate people by making them feel
meaningful?
How do you know you have made progress and improvement as
a differentiator?
What are reasons employees might enjoy being a differentiator?
Differentiation Strategy
Product Characteristics
Unique, special, premium
High service, new product launches
Acceptable price
Goal
Increase perception of value
Capture perception with higher prices
Resources are focused on
Creating higher value
Marketing & Promotion
Innovation/ Exploration
Differentiation Response to Five Forces
Threat of Rivalry
customer’s brand loyalty to differentiated product offsets price
competition
Power of Buyers
well differentiated products reduce customer sensitivity to price
increases
Power of Suppliers
absorb price increases due to higher margins
pass along higher supplier prices due to buyer loyalty
Differentiation Response to Five Forces
Threat of New Entrants
differentiation sets a high bar on performance and brand
Threat of Substitutes
brand loyalty to a differentiated product tends to reduce
customers’ testing of new products or switching brands
Competitive Risks of Differentiation
The price differential between the differentiator’s product and
the cost leader’s product becomes too large
Differentiation ceases to provide value for which customers are
willing to pay
Experience narrows customers’ perceptions of the value of
differentiated features
Counterfeit goods replicate the differentiated features of the
firm’s products
For next week…
Complete Case Paper #3 on Aldi
Due at our next class March 19th
Focused on Cost Leadership and Differentiation Strategies.
NO Blue Ocean!
NO Business Models
Focus on Chapter 6
(After tonight – 0 class till Spring Break)
29
WPC 480.
Week 10
1
Upcoming Assignments
Quiz 5 – Chapter 8 March 26th - Due today
Quiz 6 – Chapter 9 April 2nd
Quiz 7 – Chapter 12 April 9th
SAS Paper #4 – April 16th
Quiz 8 – Chapter 10 April 23rd
Group Analysis Paper – April 23rd
Exec Interview Presentation – April 30th
Final Exam – May 7th Thursday 6 PM to 7:50 PM
2
For next week…
Topic: Corporate Strategy: Mergers & Acquisitions…
Textbook Reading: Chapter 9
Quiz #6 over Chapter 9 due April 2nd
Need volunteer for Chapter 9 mini-case presentation on Lyft.
(After tonight – 6 classes till end of semester)
3
Growth
4
Growth Options
Diversification – Increase in variety
Vertical Integration – Forward or Backward on value chain
5
Industry 1
Diversification
Industry 2
Vertical Integration
Diversification
6
7
8
Related Diversification
Firms create value by building upon or extending:
resources
capabilities
core competencies
Economies of Scope
Cost savings that occur when a firm transfers capabilities and
competencies developed in one of its businesses to another of
its businesses
Economies of Scope
Operational EoS: Shared activities or leveraging core
competencies or transferring skills among units
Financial EoS: Internal capital markets – moving capital
between units.
(The only EoS that unrelated diversification can accomplish)
Honda
11
Manufacturing Platforms
Innovation Activities
Shared Activities
Lightweight, reliable engines
Realized as Diversification
Stand alone
Marine
Vehicles
Yard Care
Generators
Boats Watercraft
Cars, SUV, Vans
Lawn mowers Snow Blowers
Core Products
Building Core Competencies
Firms can diversify to build new competencies to transform the
corporation
12
Restructuring
Guide to Structure: Growth/Share Matrix
Different investment strategies
13
Firm Performance
14
Vertical Intregation
15
Growth Options
Diversification – Increase in variety
Vertical Integration – Forward or Backward on value chain
16
Industry 1
Diversification
Industry 2
Vertical Integration
Vertical Integration
17
Make or Buy?
When firms are more efficient than the market then consider
vertical integration
18
Transaction Costs
External transaction costs
Searching for a firm or individual with which to contract
Negotiating, monitoring, supervising and enforcing the contract
Internal transaction costs
Recruiting and retaining employees
Paying salaries and benefits
Setting up a shop floor
Providing office space and computers, etc.
Risk of Opportunisum: greatest with asset specificity problems
Make or Buy?
20
$4.80 Foods
(Mozzarella Cheese)
Where your pizza comes from
Dairy Farmers
(milk)
Crop Farmers
(Alfalfa & Corn)
Seed Companies
(Alfalfa & Corn)
Food Distributors
Pizza Chains
End Consumer
Value Chain
21
$4.80 Foods
(Mozzarella Cheese)
Dairy Farmers
(milk)
Crop Farmers
(Alfalfa & Corn)
Seed Companies
(Alfalfa & Corn)
Food Distributors
Pizza Chains
End Consumer
Backward
Vertical
Integration
Forward
Vertical
Integration
Vertical Integration
22
Activity
Determine how diversified your company is per the matrix?
How have they diversified?
Have they vertically integrated? From what starting point and
in what direction?
Selected Companies
24
Value Creation vs Costs
25
26
WPC 480.
Week 7
1
For next week…
Topic: Differentiation & Niches based on readings below…
Textbook Reading:
Chapter 6, Chapter 5 (pgs 165 – 171)
Submit an article on a corporate merger or acquisition that’s not
completed yet if you haven’t.
(After tonight – 1 class till Spring Break)
2
Team Presentation
Strategy
Mission: A firm’s long term purpose – what it aspires to be and
what it will avoid in the meantime.
Objectives: Specific measurable targets a firm can use to
evaluate the extent to which it is realizing its mission.
Strategy
What is strategy?
Your strategy is your theory of how to excel at the game you are
playing
A firm’s strategy is its theory of how to achieve high levels of
performance in the markets and industries within which it is
operating.
Strategy is a position:
Combine resources & capabilities that ‘position’ your firm in
the industry
Different positions in the industry are subject to distinct 5-
forces
Generic strategies:
Differentiation – design strategies with core competencies to
increase willingness to pay for target customers more than it
increase costs for the firm
Cost-leadership – design strategies with core competencies to
lower costs for the firm by more than it decreases willingness to
pay for target customers
Strategy
Blue Ocean Strategy
7
Blue Ocean Strategy
Value Innovation: Aligning consumer utility, price and cost for
maximizing value to company and consumer – product
differentiation and low cost.
8
Business-level Strategies
Customer Focus
Key Issues in Business-level Strategy
Who will be served?
What needs will be satisfied?
How will those needs be satisfied?
Tradeoffs (stop imitators)
Triad necessary for successful strategy
Strong Positioning (competitive strategy) creates guides for
making tradeoffs and creating organizations that fit
Consistent tradeoffs create an organization that fits a
competitive strategy and helps create barriers to competition
Fit creates capabilities and resources that can be a guide to
creating a strategy and making tradeoffs.
Positioning (vs competitors)
Fit (inside & outside)
The Triad
Cost leadership
Confusing name – it really is about having the lowest price in
your industry
Generally low price requires lowest costs everywhere, but
lowest prices are relative to competitors (so could be high
absolute costs in some cases)
Sources of keeping costs down and prices low
Cost of input factors (supplier power matters here)
Economies of scale
Employing specialized systems and equipment
Minimum efficient scale – increases in volume do not lead to
further cost reductions
Implies large market share almost always to get the best
economies of scale
8
Cost leadership:
It takes time to reduce costs
Learning Curve Effects – price drops (and quality increases) as
volume increases over time
Versus Economy of Scales: Economy of Scales are a specific
points in time versus accumulation over time
Differences in Complexity: Depending on product/service EoS
may have stronger impacts than learning curves
Experience Curve Effects – price drops (and quality increases)
with changes in technology of production
Process Innovation: changes in technology allow increased
efficiency with same output volume.
Technology can be changes in methods or machinery
9
Cost leadership:
It takes time to reduce costs
Cost Leadership requires optimization of value chain overall,
not just single steps
Supplier/buyer relationships matter
May increase costs in one step to lower them overall
Ex: a costly automated packaging line lowers costs when
demand is variable/grows
Cost reductions must not threaten to impact product or service
quality – they should increase or maintain quality
9
Cost leadership:
Discipline in managing growth
Growth can cause diseconomies of scale also
Example: increasing layers of hierarchy as firm grows if it
doesn’t decentralize
Success does not, generally, lead to people being “tighter” with
money
Have to fight the impulse to start adding extra costs because
doing well
Success can lead to a sense of higher status which can lead to
increased spending to match new status
Discipline includes unchanging rules about what to NOT to do
Example: never increase profits when costs go down; keep
margins the same
Prohibitions on specific actions are easier to follow and
communicate than abstract goals
10
Cost Leadership: Requires a culture of discipline and long view
of time
Needs to be a value everyone agrees upon to keep prices and
costs low
Continuous improvement only comes from a long-term
commitment
Top management has to keep focus to avoid growth traps and
getting “stuck in the middle”
11
Cost Leadership Strategy
Product Characteristics
Relatively standardized (commoditized) products
Features broadly acceptable to many customers
Lowest competitive price
Goal
Reduce the firm’s cost below its competitors
Offer adequate value
Resources are focused on
Reducing cost/ exploiting efficiencies
Reducing prices for customers
Activity
18
Create a 2x2 with the company and the competitors – Value on
one axis and your choice on the other axis
Tell us the factors aligned with the Cost Leadership Strategy.
Supported with examples with activities, resources or
capabilities
How did they build or acquire these?
19
Activity
Auto Industry – Hynduai, Kia
Hotels – MicroTel, Motel 6
Mattresses – Casper, Tuft&Needle
Real Estate Listings – Redfin
Car Care – JiffyLube
Personal Care Products – Razors
Car Rentals – Budget
20
Cost Response to Five Forces
Threat of Rivalry
rivals hesitate to compete on basis of price
lack of price competition leads to greater profits
Power of Buyers
drives prices far below competitors, causing them to exit, thus
shifting power with buyers (customers) back to the firm
increase switching costs
Power of Suppliers
able to absorb cost increases due to low cost position.
able to make very large purchases, reducing chance of supplier
using power
Cost Response to Five Forces
Threat of New Entrants
enter on a large scale in order to be cost competitive
increase the time it takes to move down the industry learning
curve
Threat of Substitutes
lower prices in order to maintain its value position
make investments to add features unavailable in substitutes
Risks of Cost Leadership Strategy
Processes used may become obsolete
Erosion of Margins
Competitors catch up and erode cost leader’s advantage
Competitors shift consumer focus to non-price attributes
Competitors, using their own core competencies, may
successfully imitate the cost leader’s strategy
Cost reductions may occur at expense of customers’ perceptions
of value (cheap)
07-042
July 25, 2007
This case was prepared by Professor Rebecca M. Henderson,
Joel Conkling and Scott Roberts. Professor Henderson is the
Eastman Kodak Leaders for Manufacturing Professor of
Management
Copyright © 2007, Rebecca M. Henderson. This work is
licensed under the Creative Commons Attribution-
Noncommercial-No
Derivative Works 3.0 Unported License. To view a copy of this
license visit http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by-nc-nd/3.0/
or send a letter to Creative Commons, 171 Second Street, Suite
300, San Francisco, California, 94105, USA.
SunPower: Focused on the Future of Solar Power
Rebecca M. Henderson, Joel Conkling and Scott Roberts
It was December 2006. Tom Werner, CEO of SunPower, glanced
down at his watch and shook his
head in dismay. His run was not going well, despite the sounds
of John Lee Hooker’s “Boogie
Chillen” coming through his earphones. He blamed the board
meeting later that afternoon.
Given SunPower’s position as the producer of the world’s most
efficient solar cells, also known as
photovoltaics or PV, and recent forecasts that solar power might
be on the edge of explosive growth,
he knew that he’d be asked some tough questions. Werner
wondered how fast the solar power
industry was likely to grow and how long SunPower’s
advantage was likely to last. How could
SunPower compete with much larger companies like Sharp and
Q-Cells? Or with the niche
“technology play” firms that were springing up? How could
SunPower’s current advantage be turned
into an enduring competitive edge?
As the sun began to rise, Werner picked up the pace again, and
began jogging home.
Environmental Issues
One of the most important drivers of the world’s renewed
interest in solar power was its ability to
offer energy independence in combination with significant
environmental benefits. After all, the earth
received more energy from the sun than humans consumed
throughout an entire year. Since the
burning of fossil fuels generated a number of noxious
substances including SO2, NO, NO2, and
particulates, concerns for human and environmental health had
driven interest in solar power from its
earliest days. But evidence that rising concentrations of CO2 in
the earth’s atmosphere could pose
large long-term environmental risks had significantly increased
interest in the technology.
SUNPOWER: FOCUSED ON THE FUTURE OF SOLAR
POWER
Rebecca M. Henderson, Joel Conkling and Scott Roberts
July 25, 2007 2
For over a century, scientists had observed the “greenhouse
effect,” the warming of the earth caused
by the atmosphere’s increased absorption of infrared radiation
resulting from increased concentrations
of CO2 and other greenhouse gases in the atmosphere.
Levels of CO2 had risen from around 280 parts per million
volume (ppmv) before the industrial
revolution to 380ppmv in 2006 higher than at any point in more
than half a million years. Data
presented in the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change’s
(IPCC) 4th Assessment Report, a 6-
year study on global warming involving 2,500 leading scientists
from 100 countries, provided even
more alarming statistics. For example:
• Greenhouse gases rose 70% between 1970 and 2004 (28.7 to
49 billion tones per year in
carbon dioxide).
• CO2, which accounted for more than 75% of emissions,
increased by 80% between 1970 and
2004.
• Developed countries while accounting for 20% of the global
population, contributed 46% of
global greenhouse gas emissions.
• Greenhouse gases were projected to increase between 20% and
90% by 2030 unless
significant changes in global energy policies were made.
Looking longer-term, many studies suggested that increasing
concentrations of green house gases
greatly increased the odds of catastrophic climate change. One
study published in the journal Nature
predicted that temperature increases of 3.24–3.6°F and CO2
increases to 500–550 ppmv would result
in the extinction of 1,000,000 terrestrial species (25% of all
land animals and plants) by 2050.1
Meanwhile, average global temperatures had already risen
1.33°F since 1906—and polar
temperatures were rising faster still.
Most scientists believed that the stabilization of CO2 levels was
urgently required, but just what
concentration constituted a “sustainable” CO2 level was a
matter of some uncertainty. The IPCC
report suggested three scenarios (Table A) for emission
stabilization by 2030 and the impact such
cuts would have on global warming and world GDP growth.
Table A Stabilization Scenarios
Emission Output Rise in Global
Warming
Cost to Annual GDP
Growth in 2030
Scenario A 445-535 parts per million (ppm) 3.6 - 5.0°F 0.12%
Scenario B 535-590 ppm 5.0 - 5.8°F 0.1%
Scenario C 590-710 ppm 5.8 - 7.2°F 0.06%
31 Marinez Ferreira de Siqueira, Alan Grainger, et al.,
“Extinction Risk from Climate Change,” Nature, January 8,
2004,
427, p. 145-148.
SUNPOWER: FOCUSED ON THE FUTURE OF SOLAR
POWER
Rebecca M. Henderson, Joel Conkling and Scott Roberts
July 25, 2007 3
Scenario A, involving the most aggressive action, would result
in a 3% cumulative cost to annual
world GDP growth by 2030. At 2006 growth rates, however,
global concentrations would reach 800
ppmv by the end of the 21st century.
A sense of urgency about global warming had prompted many
countries to search for aggressive,
coordinated strategies to reduce CO2 emissions. (Table B gives
CO2 emissions for electricity
production by fuel type.) The most far-reaching attempt, the
Kyoto Protocol, committed a number of
countries to modest CO2 reductions by a 2012 deadline. As part
of this “emission cap” approach,
some signatories allocated CO2 emissions allowances to
individual firms. The Kyoto Protocol
permitted these allowances to be traded across borders, creating
a “carbon market.” For example, a
Spanish factory might find it profitable to reduce its emissions
by a given amount and sell the
allowances to another factory in Italy that planned to exceed its
own quota. Even signatories that had
not committed to emissions cuts could participate. These
countries—mainly large developing
countries such as China and India—could forgo emissions and
sell them as credits to customers in
other countries.
Table B CO2 Emissions for Electricity Production
Generation Type Tons CO2 per MWh
Nuclear 0
Hydro power 0
Coal 0.999
Oil 0.942
Gas 0.439
Geothermal, Solar, Tide, Wave,
Ocean, Wind, Waste and other
0
Source: CANMET Energy Technologie Centre 2
The advent of carbon trading in Europe had generated a large
market. In the first half of 2006, over
US$15 billion worth of carbon emissions were traded, five times
more than the amount the year
before,3 and CO2 trading schemes in the United States were
being developed at the state level. As of
2006, renewable sources provided 13% of the world’s energy
needs,4 while photovoltaic systems
provided a mere .04% of the world’s electricity. The U.S.
Department of Energy estimated that the
country could supply its entire energy needs by covering .5% of
its land area with solar cells.5
2 Cited in B. Gaiddon, M. Jedliczka, Environmental Benefits of
PV Systems in OECD Cities, September 2006.
3 Economist, “Selling Hot Air”, September 7, 2006.
4 “Sunlit Uplands,” The Economist, June 2, 2007.
5 “Sunlit Uplands,” The Economist, June 2, 2007.
SUNPOWER: FOCUSED ON THE FUTURE OF SOLAR
POWER
Rebecca M. Henderson, Joel Conkling and Scott Roberts
July 25, 2007 4
Solar Power Industry
Solar cell, or photovoltaic (PV) systems converted energy from
the sun into electric current. Solar
cell performance was measured in terms of conversion
efficiency, the proportion of solar energy
converted to electricity. The first commercial solar cells were
introduced in the 1950s by Bell Labs,
and had efficiencies below 4%.6 In 2006, PV efficiencies
ranged from 10%-20% and some scientists
believed that further research, combined with advances in
installation methods, could push
conversion efficiencies well over 20%, with 50% seen as the
long-term “holy grail.”7
A typical solar cell produced about 0.5V — roughly one-third of
a regular AA battery, far too small
to be of any practical use by itself — and cells were thus
combined in larger blocks, called modules.
Although modules varied in size, they typically included 72
cells, and yielded between 30-45V.
Once constructed, modules were typically combined in arrays or
panels which were then integrated
with “inverters” – sophisticated devices that converted the DC
power output of the solar panels or
arrays into the AC power used in conventional electrical
appliances.
While solar power was two to three times as expensive as the
retail cost of electricity,8 the market
continued to grow at a steep upward trajectory. As Figure 1
shows, module manufacturing began to
ramp up a few years after module prices hit a plateau. (Exhibit 1
provides yearly production and
price data spanning 1975 to 2005.) Solar photovoltaic power
grew an average of 41% each year
between 2003 and 2006,9 and was expected to grow 40%
annually through 2011. Industry profits
were expected to top $7.7 billion in 2007 and $11.5 billion by
2011.10 Roughly $1.7 billion in
private equity and venture capital funds went into the industry
in 2006 and another $4.5 billion was
invested in publicly traded solar companies, most of it going
toward expanding manufacturing
capacity.11
6 http://www.nrel.gov/learning/re_photovoltaics.html
7 Vaclav Smil, 2003. Energy at the Crossroads, Cambridge:
MIT Press, p. 288.
8 “Bright Prospects,” The Economist, March 8, 2007.
9 “Sunlit Uplands,” The Economist, June 2, 2007.
10 Liz Skinner, “Sun Will Shine on Solar-Energy Investing,
Report Says,” Investment News, June 18, 2007.
11 Cassidy Flanagan, “New Light on Solar Energy,” Business
Week, May 17, 2007.
SUNPOWER: FOCUSED ON THE FUTURE OF SOLAR
POWER
Rebecca M. Henderson, Joel Conkling and Scott Roberts
Figure 1 PV Module Price and Production History, 1975-2005
PV Module Price History
$0.00
$5.00
$10.00
$15.00
$20.00
$25.00
$30.00
$35.00
19
75
19
80
19
85
19
90
19
95
19
96
19
97
19
98
19
99
20
00
20
01
20
02
20
03
20
04
20
05
U
S
$/
w
at
t
PV Module Annual Production
0
200
400
600
800
1000
1200
1400
1600
1800
2000
19
75
19
80
19
85
19
90
19
95
19
96
19
97
19
98
19
99
20
00
20
01
20
02
20
03
20
04
20
05
M
W
Source: Maycock.
July 25, 2007 5
SUNPOWER: FOCUSED ON THE FUTURE OF SOLAR
POWER
Rebecca M. Henderson, Joel Conkling and Scott Roberts
Producers and Consumers
Japan was the world’s PV shipment leader, shipping more than
five times the volume of the United
States (Figure 2). Since 2002, Europe had held the number two
position after it passed the United
States and by 2005, Europe was shipping three times the volume
of the United States. Analysts
blamed the erosion of U.S. PV market share to a lack of
manufacturing incentives and high
manufacturing costs.
Figure 2 Global PV Shipments, 2000-2005
Global PV Shipments
0
100
200
300
400
500
600
700
800
M
W
p
U.S.
Japan
Europe
ROW
U.S. 76.2 96.7 107.8 91.5 140.6 133.6
Japan 96.3 145 233.8 350.6 547 714
Europe 58.5 85.4 123.4 173.1 272.9 406.9
ROW 22 25.8 39.9 60 89.2 153.2
2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005
Source: Paula Mints, “PV in the U.S.: Where is the market
going and how will it get there?”, Renewable Energy Watch,
September 2006.
Analysts’ expectations that China was the market to watch due
to its growing energy needs, large
work force and strong industrial base were proven correct in
2006 when China surpassed the United
States as the world’s third largest producer of PV cells, behind
Germany and Japan. Lacking any kind
of domestic incentive/subsidy policy, more than 90% of China’s
PV products were exported. Chinese
PV producers raised billions of dollars in international IPOs in
2005 and 2006 to build capacity and
increase scale with the goal of driving down costs.12
On the consumer side, global PV demand had grown from 114
MWp in 1997 to 505 MWp in 2002 to
1,408MWp in 2005 and 2,500MWp in 2006 and demand was
accelerating rapidly particularly in
Europe (most especially Germany) and Japan as shown in
Figure 3. One prominent analysis of
12 Gail Roberts, “Production Trends and New Technologies
Could Push Solar Energy into Mainstream,” Electric Utility
Weekly, May 28, 2007.
July 25, 2007 6
SUNPOWER: FOCUSED ON THE FUTURE OF SOLAR
POWER
Rebecca M. Henderson, Joel Conkling and Scott Roberts
potential demand at 2006module prices—i.e., around $3.50-
$4.50/W with policy support—estimated
that there was potential worldwide demand of approximately
5,000MWp, or double 2006 industry
sales. Meanwhile, global grid-connected solar capacity was
about 5,000MWp. In contrast, installed
wind capacity in the United States alone was 9,149MWp.13
Figure 3 Global PV Demand, 2000-2005
Global PV Demand
0
100
200
300
400
500
600
700
800
M
W
p
U.S.
Japan
Europe
ROW
U.S. 34.7 43.8 60.8 76 101.8 137.3
Japan 77.9 109.8 176.2 243.8 295.9 392.4
Europe 74.1 120 172.6 232.6 472.4 676.1
ROW 65.3 79.2 95.3 122.9 179.7 202
2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005
Source: Paula Mints, “PV in the U.S.: Where is the market
going and how will it get there?”, Renewable Energy Watch,
September 2006.
The Solar Value Chain
There were five key stages in solar power’s value chain: silicon
production, ingot/wafer manufacture,
solar cell manufacture, solar module manufacture, and system
installation. Firms in the industry
differed dramatically in the degree to which they participated in
each stage. (Table C shows
revenues and profits across the chain.)
Table C PV Industry Value Chain Snapshot
Year: 2006 Silicon Ingots/Wafers Cells Modules Installatio
n
# of players 20 40 100 500 5,000
Revenues ($m) 1,400 4,500 7,700 10,200 3,200
Pre-tax margin (%) 53 36 21 5 20
Capital costs ($/w/year) 0.65 0.50 0.05
Source: Solar Annual 2006
13 Gail Roberts, “Production Trends and New Technologies
Could Push Solar Energy into Mainstream,” Electric Utility
Week, May 28, 2007.
July 25, 2007 7
SUNPOWER: FOCUSED ON THE FUTURE OF SOLAR
POWER
Rebecca M. Henderson, Joel Conkling and Scott Roberts
July 25, 2007 8
Silicon The key feedstock in the PV industry was high-purity
silicon, which was the basis for
more than 90% of solar modules. Silicon was obtained from
sand through a complex process using
numerous purification steps and temperatures up to 1,100ºC
which would turn sand into the high
purity silicon known as polysilicon.14
As recently as the early 2000s, solar cell producers sourced
silicon feedstock mainly from waste
silicon discarded during semiconductor manufacturing. This
“leftover” silicon supply included high-
purity silicon that was slightly above or below the quality
specified for semiconductor production, or
off-cuts (tops or tails) of monocrystalline ingots. For their part,
silicon producers had historically
considered solar cell makers a market of last resort, useful for
stabilizing fluctuations in the overall
semiconductor market but unlikely to amount to meaningful
scale.
The explosive growth of PV cell manufacturing, however, had
transformed the role of solar power in
the silicon business. In 2005, the solar industry used
approximately 47% of available silicon, and in
2006 it would likely account for the majority share. These fast
growing needs had stretched global
silicon supply and prices had risen dramatically from
$32/kilogram in 2004 under a long-term
contract, to $45/kg in 2005, to a predicted $55/kg in 2006 with
short-term contracts exceeding
$200/kg. However, current investment plans would triple
capacity, from 31,000 tons per year in 2005
to 100,000 tons or more by 2010,15 despite the fact that a 5,000
tons/year expansion cost roughly $300
million. The silicon shortage was expected to end around 2008
when supply was estimated to grow
70%.16
Ingots / Wafers Many large solar cell manufacturers had in-
house ingot production and wafer
sawing capabilities, including REC, SolarWorld, Kyocera, and
BP Solar. Dedicated ingot and wafer
manufacturers supplied wafers to the solar cell manufacturers
that did not have their own ingot and
wafer capabilities. Technical progress in the industry had been
rapid. In 2004 typical wafers were
250-300 microns thick, and by 2006 they were around 190
microns. However over the same period
prices had risen dramatically. In 2004 wafers were sold for
around $1.00/watt, while in 2005 the
average price was $1.25/watt and in 2006 it was expected to be
$1.90/watt.
Cells and Modules Solar cell manufacturing was a widely
understood process that involved less
than ten steps. The largest producers, which included Sharp
Solar (Japan), Q-Cells (Germany),
Kyocera (Japan), Sanyo (Japan), and Mitsubishi Electric
(Japan), together accounted for roughly 58%
of the market. Sharp was the clear market leader, with 427.5
MW of production in 2005, nearly three
times that of its nearest competitor. Between 50 and 100
manufacturers made up the rest of the
industry’s production capacity.
14 Million Roofs handout
15 Policysilicon: Supply, Demand, & Implications for the PV
Industry, Prometheus Institute, 2006.
16 Brian Womack, “Alternative Energy Sun Shines on Clean
Energy,” Investor’s Business Daily, May 21, 2007.
SUNPOWER: FOCUSED ON THE FUTURE OF SOLAR
POWER
Rebecca M. Henderson, Joel Conkling and Scott Roberts
July 25, 2007 9
Due to the global silicon shortage, solar cell prices rose from
$2.70/watt in 2004 to $2.50/watt in
2005, and were forecast by Photon Consulting to rise to
$3.25/watt in 2006. At expected 2006 prices,
pre-tax cell manufacturing profit margins were expected by
Photon Consulting to be 21%. While
there were roughly 500 smaller module manufacturers in
operation in 2006, most of the top cell
manufacturers made modules as well. In parallel with increases
in PV cell prices, average module
prices had also risen from $3.20/watt in 2004 to $3.75/watt in
2005, and were expected to reach
$4.30/watt in 2006.
System Installation / Integration The most advanced systems
integrators had expertise
in installing megawatt-scale solar systems at low costs in fields
and on large commercial roofs.
Competition for these large projects was fierce, and margins
were tight even for the best integrators.
On the other side of the installation spectrum, small residential
installers made up the majority of the
5,000+ solar installers and integrators in operation. In general
costs and prices varied widely,
depending on the application and geographical region. Total
installation costs ranged from $1/watt to
$3/watt, and consumer prices ranged from $1.25/watt to
$4/watt. For dual-axis trackers in large field
installations, area-related costs could reach $1.50-$2.00 per
watt, while commercial flat roofs, where
aesthetics were less important, were usually around $0.60 per
watt. Residential roof installations cost
approximately $1.00 per watt for area related costs.
While solar installation was fairly simple at a very basic level
(one secured racks to the roof and then
attached modules to the racks and plugged them in), there could
be meaningful first mover advantage
for installers that developed expertise in an end-consumer
market. For example, the installer that put
a system in for a Best Buy could be rewarded with lower costs
selling to other ‘big box’ retailers
because it understood both the sales process and the needs of
that type of customer. Similarly an
installer that developed expertise in, for example, residential
installations in San Diego, could develop
lower costs in residential installation in San Diego than
potential entrants.
Pricing
Deriving an exact price for solar generated electricity was
tricky. While conventional power was sold
as a flow of power from the grid in units of $/kWhr, solar power
was typically sold as an installed
system with an upfront capital cost measured in units of $/peak
watt. Deriving a flow cost — how
much the user would actually pay for kWhrs and how much they
would pay per installed watt of
generating capacity — depended on a wide range of factors
including the life of the system, interest
rates, subsidies (if any), hours of sunshine and so on. Hours of
sunshine, for example, ranged from
nearly six per day in parts of Southern California to 2.5 hours
per day in parts of Northern Europe,
with important seasonal variation – and both interest rates and
the subsidies given to solar power
varied widely across the world.
SUNPOWER: FOCUSED ON THE FUTURE OF SOLAR
POWER
Rebecca M. Henderson, Joel Conkling and Scott Roberts
In general, however, the average price of solar power ranged
from US 25-50¢ per kWh. For example,
as Exhibit 2 suggests, the average cost of a residential PV
system in California translated into an
electricity price, without subsidies, of roughly 31¢/kWh. In
contrast, one could generate electricity
using conventional power sources for between 4¢/kWh and
6¢/kWh (Exhibit 3). Final prices to the
consumer could be significantly higher because electricity was
expensive to distribute, but on average
conventionally generated electricity was still significantly
cheaper than solar power. According to the
Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development
(OECD), prices for household customers
started at just several cents per kWh in areas of Scandinavia and
rose to over 25¢/kWh in the highest-
priced markets such as Japan. The U.S. average was 9.6¢/kWh
in early 2006, with California prices
averaging over 13¢/kWh.
As Exhibit 4 suggests, however, the average price of electricity
told only part of the story. In
markets around the world, some customers paid significantly
more than the average price of
electricity. In California, for example, commercial customers
paid 24% more per kWh than
residential customers. Meanwhile, the state further stratified
prices into five tiers based on total
electricity usage per month. As Figure 4 shows, a California
customer that consumed more than 34
kWh per day would pay 37¢, Tier 5 prices, for every kWh over
the 34 kWh/day limit of Tier 4.
Figure 4 California Residential Power Pricing Structure,
September 2006
-
0.0 5
0.1 0
0.1 5
0.2 0
0.2 5
0.3 0
0.3 5
0.4 0
- 5 1 0 14 19 24 29 34 38 43 48
k W h p e r d a y
A ve ra g e
H o u se h o ld
C o n su m p tio n
T ier 1 T ier 2
T ier 3
T ie r 4
T ier 5
cen ts
p e r
kW h
Source: Pacific Gas and Electric.
Given its high cost, up until the late 1990s, most PV power was
used to meet the demands of “off the
grid” users. Since that time, however, more solar panels had
been sold to residential customers than
any other single segment. Panels, attached to the roof of a house
or apartment building, could in many
cases give households full or near self-sufficiency in power
supply. In markets that permitted net
metering, households also had the option to sell their excess
power to the grid. Under favorable
July 25, 2007 10
SUNPOWER: FOCUSED ON THE FUTURE OF SOLAR
POWER
Rebecca M. Henderson, Joel Conkling and Scott Roberts
July 25, 2007 11
pricing (“feed-in tariffs”), this option could dramatically
improve the economics of a home PV
system.
Increasingly, solar systems were also finding a market among
large commercial facilities such as big
box retail stores, shopping malls, hospitals, and airports. In
most cases, solar cells were not
substituted completely for grid-based electricity, and customers
continued to purchase from the
commercial grid. Some commercial customers installed PV
systems as a hedge against high
electricity prices while others recognized the potential public
relations benefits of a “green power”
investment. Utility-scale applications were once regarded as
the main potential market for solar
power. Until the late 1990s, for example, parabolic
concentrators at three sites in California’s Mojave
Desert accounted for more than 90% of the world’s installed
solar capacity.17 However operational
and financial challenges had made this vision obsolete. The
firm that built the Mojave facilities, Luz
International, went out of business. Solar towers were also slow
to take off and only a few
experimental facilities, mostly under 1 MW, had opened in
California, Spain, Israel, Germany, and
Australia.18
Policy Support
Solar power’s potential to increase energy independence and
reduce carbon emissions had led to a
wide variety of public subsidies. Around the world, there were
more than 1,000 various pro-solar
policies put in place by international, national, and local
authorities. California’s “Million Solar
Roofs” initiative, for example, had allocated $3.2 billion for
solar power “buy-downs” through 2016.
(A buy-down reduced the upfront capital expenditure required
to install a solar system.) In some
jurisdictions, customers could sell excess solar power back to
their utility at favorable prices. Some
governments had set specific targets for the number of
households with PV systems, or renewable
portfolio standards (RPS) which required utilities to derive a
targeted percentage of power from
renewable sources and/or solar power. In South Korea, for
example, government mandated a target
of 1,300 MW of solar power installations by 2012 and in the
United States, 24 states had
implemented their own RPS. (See Exhibit 5 for list of standards
by state.)
The U.S. solar market was highly diverse. State regulations and
policies toward solar power ranged
from the supportive to the non-existent, and power prices, the
availability of solar radiation, and
public attitudes toward the environment also varied dramatically
across states. Exhibit 6 compares
the costs and savings for a solar system installed in California,
Texas and Massachusetts based on the
same monthly electric usage. While a California resident’s
estimated net cost would be roughly
$17,480, a Massachusetts resident would likely pay nearly twice
that amount. Meanwhile, rebates and
credits in the state of California ($18,250) equaled half of the
installation price. In Texas they were
38% and in Massachusetts 23%.
17 Smil, p.285
18 Ibid.
SUNPOWER: FOCUSED ON THE FUTURE OF SOLAR
POWER
Rebecca M. Henderson, Joel Conkling and Scott Roberts
July 25, 2007 12
Quantifying public subsidy policies into a global total of pro-
solar spending was difficult, but one
analysis estimated that a total of $1.7 billion was spent by
governments worldwide in 2005 in
supporting solar power, and that this figure would surpass $3
billion in 2006.19 For companies like
SunPower subsidy programs were critical in generating demand.
But analysts believed that the
industry would be able to prop itself up without subsidies by
2012.20 Of course the key to doing so
was lowering costs and scaling up production.
SunPower
SunPower was founded in 1987 by Dr. Richard Swanson, a
professor of electrical engineering at
Stanford University. At the time it closed its Series A round of
VC financing in 1989, SunPower’s
goal was to commercialize solar concentrator21 technology.
However, according to Swanson, the
company ended up going in a different direction:
We realized that solar concentrators were a bad idea.
Conceivably, someday concentrator systems
could be a lower-cost PV alternative, but they are not now and
they have a long way to catch up
with continually improving flat-plate systems. Moreover,
concentrators are not well suited for
many small distributed, remote applications. We wrestled with
whether we should give the
money back to the VCs or not. Ultimately, we chose not to.
Starting in about 1991, SunPower
went through a long period of trying to find its way.
In the early 1990s, the Honda Motor Company approached
SunPower asking if the company, known
for its efficient solar cells, could make cells big enough to
cover Honda’s solar powered race car.
After agreeing to Honda’s request, Swanson realized there was
one barrier standing in the way of
SunPower’s ability to deliver: “We were all from academia. We
argued for about four hours one day
about whether we needed two shifts or one shift and realized
after a while we had no idea how to
figure out whether we needed two shifts or one shift.”
After hearing about SunPower’s dilemma, …

More Related Content

Similar to 261Megaregion Planningand High-Speed RailPetra Tod.docx

Andrew - Allegheny County Transit Analysis
Andrew - Allegheny County Transit AnalysisAndrew - Allegheny County Transit Analysis
Andrew - Allegheny County Transit AnalysisAndrew Ritchie
 
National Rail Budget Analysis
National Rail Budget AnalysisNational Rail Budget Analysis
National Rail Budget AnalysisKaren Oliver
 
Off Track: Sub-Saharan African Railways
Off Track: Sub-Saharan African RailwaysOff Track: Sub-Saharan African Railways
Off Track: Sub-Saharan African RailwaysDr Lendy Spires
 
Transportation Technology for the 21st Century
Transportation Technology for the 21st CenturyTransportation Technology for the 21st Century
Transportation Technology for the 21st CenturyIBM Government
 
Transportation Technology for a Smarter System
Transportation Technology for a Smarter SystemTransportation Technology for a Smarter System
Transportation Technology for a Smarter SystemIBMTransportation
 
AMajor Traffic Street Planfor Los AngelesPrepare.docx
AMajor Traffic Street Planfor Los AngelesPrepare.docxAMajor Traffic Street Planfor Los AngelesPrepare.docx
AMajor Traffic Street Planfor Los AngelesPrepare.docxnettletondevon
 
Stuck in Traffic: Urban Transport in Africa
Stuck in Traffic: Urban Transport in AfricaStuck in Traffic: Urban Transport in Africa
Stuck in Traffic: Urban Transport in AfricaDr Lendy Spires
 
Economic Ecosystems - Mass Transit In The North Bay
Economic Ecosystems - Mass Transit In The North BayEconomic Ecosystems - Mass Transit In The North Bay
Economic Ecosystems - Mass Transit In The North BayJoshua Dopkowski
 
Logistics In The Roman Empire
Logistics In The Roman EmpireLogistics In The Roman Empire
Logistics In The Roman EmpireAngela Hays
 
Beyond Traffic: US DOT's 30 Year Framework for the Future
Beyond Traffic: US DOT's 30 Year Framework for the FutureBeyond Traffic: US DOT's 30 Year Framework for the Future
Beyond Traffic: US DOT's 30 Year Framework for the FutureLudovic Privat
 
Draft beyond traffic_framework
Draft beyond traffic_frameworkDraft beyond traffic_framework
Draft beyond traffic_frameworkBrendan O'Connor
 
February 2013 Update from the Ports-to-Plains Alliance
February 2013 Update from the Ports-to-Plains AllianceFebruary 2013 Update from the Ports-to-Plains Alliance
February 2013 Update from the Ports-to-Plains AlliancePorts-To-Plains Blog
 
GEOG501_Cairo_Poster_Final
GEOG501_Cairo_Poster_FinalGEOG501_Cairo_Poster_Final
GEOG501_Cairo_Poster_FinalShekhar Mote
 
Connecticut River Valley Commuter Rail Proposal
Connecticut River Valley Commuter Rail ProposalConnecticut River Valley Commuter Rail Proposal
Connecticut River Valley Commuter Rail ProposalEric Nielsen
 
Statement of Joe Kiely, Field Hearing of
Statement of Joe Kiely, Field Hearing ofStatement of Joe Kiely, Field Hearing of
Statement of Joe Kiely, Field Hearing ofPorts-To-Plains Blog
 
Transportation is a pervasive and very important pa.pdf
Transportation is a pervasive and very important pa.pdfTransportation is a pervasive and very important pa.pdf
Transportation is a pervasive and very important pa.pdffashionscollect
 

Similar to 261Megaregion Planningand High-Speed RailPetra Tod.docx (20)

Andrew - Allegheny County Transit Analysis
Andrew - Allegheny County Transit AnalysisAndrew - Allegheny County Transit Analysis
Andrew - Allegheny County Transit Analysis
 
National Rail Budget Analysis
National Rail Budget AnalysisNational Rail Budget Analysis
National Rail Budget Analysis
 
Off Track: Sub-Saharan African Railways
Off Track: Sub-Saharan African RailwaysOff Track: Sub-Saharan African Railways
Off Track: Sub-Saharan African Railways
 
Transportation Technology for the 21st Century
Transportation Technology for the 21st CenturyTransportation Technology for the 21st Century
Transportation Technology for the 21st Century
 
Transportation Technology for a Smarter System
Transportation Technology for a Smarter SystemTransportation Technology for a Smarter System
Transportation Technology for a Smarter System
 
Smart Connections - FINAL
Smart Connections - FINALSmart Connections - FINAL
Smart Connections - FINAL
 
AMajor Traffic Street Planfor Los AngelesPrepare.docx
AMajor Traffic Street Planfor Los AngelesPrepare.docxAMajor Traffic Street Planfor Los AngelesPrepare.docx
AMajor Traffic Street Planfor Los AngelesPrepare.docx
 
Stuck in Traffic: Urban Transport in Africa
Stuck in Traffic: Urban Transport in AfricaStuck in Traffic: Urban Transport in Africa
Stuck in Traffic: Urban Transport in Africa
 
Economic Ecosystems - Mass Transit In The North Bay
Economic Ecosystems - Mass Transit In The North BayEconomic Ecosystems - Mass Transit In The North Bay
Economic Ecosystems - Mass Transit In The North Bay
 
Logistics In The Roman Empire
Logistics In The Roman EmpireLogistics In The Roman Empire
Logistics In The Roman Empire
 
Beyond Traffic: US DOT's 30 Year Framework for the Future
Beyond Traffic: US DOT's 30 Year Framework for the FutureBeyond Traffic: US DOT's 30 Year Framework for the Future
Beyond Traffic: US DOT's 30 Year Framework for the Future
 
Draft beyond traffic_framework
Draft beyond traffic_frameworkDraft beyond traffic_framework
Draft beyond traffic_framework
 
February 2013 Update from the Ports-to-Plains Alliance
February 2013 Update from the Ports-to-Plains AllianceFebruary 2013 Update from the Ports-to-Plains Alliance
February 2013 Update from the Ports-to-Plains Alliance
 
GEOG501_Cairo_Poster_Final
GEOG501_Cairo_Poster_FinalGEOG501_Cairo_Poster_Final
GEOG501_Cairo_Poster_Final
 
Western Planner Article
Western Planner ArticleWestern Planner Article
Western Planner Article
 
Connecticut River Valley Commuter Rail Proposal
Connecticut River Valley Commuter Rail ProposalConnecticut River Valley Commuter Rail Proposal
Connecticut River Valley Commuter Rail Proposal
 
Statement of Joe Kiely, Field Hearing of
Statement of Joe Kiely, Field Hearing ofStatement of Joe Kiely, Field Hearing of
Statement of Joe Kiely, Field Hearing of
 
Transportation is a pervasive and very important pa.pdf
Transportation is a pervasive and very important pa.pdfTransportation is a pervasive and very important pa.pdf
Transportation is a pervasive and very important pa.pdf
 
PPC_RAILWAY_APR16
PPC_RAILWAY_APR16PPC_RAILWAY_APR16
PPC_RAILWAY_APR16
 
URBAN SYSTEMS REPORT
URBAN SYSTEMS REPORTURBAN SYSTEMS REPORT
URBAN SYSTEMS REPORT
 

More from novabroom

3 pagesAfter reading the Cybersecurity Act of 2015, address .docx
3 pagesAfter reading the Cybersecurity Act of 2015, address .docx3 pagesAfter reading the Cybersecurity Act of 2015, address .docx
3 pagesAfter reading the Cybersecurity Act of 2015, address .docxnovabroom
 
3 pages, 4 sourcesPaper detailsNeed a full retirement plan p.docx
3 pages, 4 sourcesPaper detailsNeed a full retirement plan p.docx3 pages, 4 sourcesPaper detailsNeed a full retirement plan p.docx
3 pages, 4 sourcesPaper detailsNeed a full retirement plan p.docxnovabroom
 
3 pagesThis paper should describe, as well as compare and contra.docx
3 pagesThis paper should describe, as well as compare and contra.docx3 pagesThis paper should describe, as well as compare and contra.docx
3 pagesThis paper should describe, as well as compare and contra.docxnovabroom
 
3 assignments listed below1.  In a 350 word essay, compare a.docx
3 assignments listed below1.  In a 350 word essay, compare a.docx3 assignments listed below1.  In a 350 word essay, compare a.docx
3 assignments listed below1.  In a 350 word essay, compare a.docxnovabroom
 
3 CommunicationChallengesinaDiverse,GlobalMarketpl.docx
3 CommunicationChallengesinaDiverse,GlobalMarketpl.docx3 CommunicationChallengesinaDiverse,GlobalMarketpl.docx
3 CommunicationChallengesinaDiverse,GlobalMarketpl.docxnovabroom
 
2Women with a Parasol-Madame Monet and Her SonClau.docx
2Women with a Parasol-Madame Monet and Her SonClau.docx2Women with a Parasol-Madame Monet and Her SonClau.docx
2Women with a Parasol-Madame Monet and Her SonClau.docxnovabroom
 
2The following is a list of some of the resources availabl.docx
2The following is a list of some of the resources availabl.docx2The following is a list of some of the resources availabl.docx
2The following is a list of some of the resources availabl.docxnovabroom
 
3 If you like to develop a computer-based DAQ measurement syst.docx
3  If you like to develop a computer-based DAQ measurement syst.docx3  If you like to develop a computer-based DAQ measurement syst.docx
3 If you like to develop a computer-based DAQ measurement syst.docxnovabroom
 
2BackgroundThe research focuses on investigating leaders fro.docx
2BackgroundThe research focuses on investigating leaders fro.docx2BackgroundThe research focuses on investigating leaders fro.docx
2BackgroundThe research focuses on investigating leaders fro.docxnovabroom
 
2TITLE OF PAPERDavid B. JonesColumbia Southe.docx
2TITLE OF PAPERDavid B. JonesColumbia Southe.docx2TITLE OF PAPERDavid B. JonesColumbia Southe.docx
2TITLE OF PAPERDavid B. JonesColumbia Southe.docxnovabroom
 
2To ADD names From ADD name Date ADD date Subject ADD ti.docx
2To  ADD names From  ADD name Date  ADD date Subject  ADD ti.docx2To  ADD names From  ADD name Date  ADD date Subject  ADD ti.docx
2To ADD names From ADD name Date ADD date Subject ADD ti.docxnovabroom
 
2Megan Bowen02042020 Professor Cozen Comm 146Int.docx
2Megan Bowen02042020 Professor Cozen Comm 146Int.docx2Megan Bowen02042020 Professor Cozen Comm 146Int.docx
2Megan Bowen02042020 Professor Cozen Comm 146Int.docxnovabroom
 
2From On the Advantage and Disadvantage of History for L.docx
2From On the Advantage and Disadvantage of History for L.docx2From On the Advantage and Disadvantage of History for L.docx
2From On the Advantage and Disadvantage of History for L.docxnovabroom
 
28 jOURNAL Of MULTICULTURAL COUNSELING AND DEVELOpMENT • Janua.docx
28 jOURNAL Of MULTICULTURAL COUNSELING AND DEVELOpMENT • Janua.docx28 jOURNAL Of MULTICULTURAL COUNSELING AND DEVELOpMENT • Janua.docx
28 jOURNAL Of MULTICULTURAL COUNSELING AND DEVELOpMENT • Janua.docxnovabroom
 
2Fifth Edition COMMUNITY PSYCHOLOGY.docx
2Fifth Edition   COMMUNITY PSYCHOLOGY.docx2Fifth Edition   COMMUNITY PSYCHOLOGY.docx
2Fifth Edition COMMUNITY PSYCHOLOGY.docxnovabroom
 
257Speaking of researchGuidelines for evaluating resea.docx
257Speaking of researchGuidelines for evaluating resea.docx257Speaking of researchGuidelines for evaluating resea.docx
257Speaking of researchGuidelines for evaluating resea.docxnovabroom
 
2800 word count.APA formatplagiarism free paperThe paper.docx
2800 word count.APA formatplagiarism free paperThe paper.docx2800 word count.APA formatplagiarism free paperThe paper.docx
2800 word count.APA formatplagiarism free paperThe paper.docxnovabroom
 
28 CHAPTER 4 THE CARBON FOOTPRINT CONTROVERSY Wha.docx
28  CHAPTER 4 THE CARBON FOOTPRINT CONTROVERSY  Wha.docx28  CHAPTER 4 THE CARBON FOOTPRINT CONTROVERSY  Wha.docx
28 CHAPTER 4 THE CARBON FOOTPRINT CONTROVERSY Wha.docxnovabroom
 
250 WORDS Moyer Instruments is a rapidly growing manufacturer .docx
250 WORDS Moyer Instruments is a rapidly growing manufacturer .docx250 WORDS Moyer Instruments is a rapidly growing manufacturer .docx
250 WORDS Moyer Instruments is a rapidly growing manufacturer .docxnovabroom
 
250 WORDS CITATION AND REFERNECES What is a definition of fami.docx
250 WORDS CITATION AND REFERNECES What is a definition of fami.docx250 WORDS CITATION AND REFERNECES What is a definition of fami.docx
250 WORDS CITATION AND REFERNECES What is a definition of fami.docxnovabroom
 

More from novabroom (20)

3 pagesAfter reading the Cybersecurity Act of 2015, address .docx
3 pagesAfter reading the Cybersecurity Act of 2015, address .docx3 pagesAfter reading the Cybersecurity Act of 2015, address .docx
3 pagesAfter reading the Cybersecurity Act of 2015, address .docx
 
3 pages, 4 sourcesPaper detailsNeed a full retirement plan p.docx
3 pages, 4 sourcesPaper detailsNeed a full retirement plan p.docx3 pages, 4 sourcesPaper detailsNeed a full retirement plan p.docx
3 pages, 4 sourcesPaper detailsNeed a full retirement plan p.docx
 
3 pagesThis paper should describe, as well as compare and contra.docx
3 pagesThis paper should describe, as well as compare and contra.docx3 pagesThis paper should describe, as well as compare and contra.docx
3 pagesThis paper should describe, as well as compare and contra.docx
 
3 assignments listed below1.  In a 350 word essay, compare a.docx
3 assignments listed below1.  In a 350 word essay, compare a.docx3 assignments listed below1.  In a 350 word essay, compare a.docx
3 assignments listed below1.  In a 350 word essay, compare a.docx
 
3 CommunicationChallengesinaDiverse,GlobalMarketpl.docx
3 CommunicationChallengesinaDiverse,GlobalMarketpl.docx3 CommunicationChallengesinaDiverse,GlobalMarketpl.docx
3 CommunicationChallengesinaDiverse,GlobalMarketpl.docx
 
2Women with a Parasol-Madame Monet and Her SonClau.docx
2Women with a Parasol-Madame Monet and Her SonClau.docx2Women with a Parasol-Madame Monet and Her SonClau.docx
2Women with a Parasol-Madame Monet and Her SonClau.docx
 
2The following is a list of some of the resources availabl.docx
2The following is a list of some of the resources availabl.docx2The following is a list of some of the resources availabl.docx
2The following is a list of some of the resources availabl.docx
 
3 If you like to develop a computer-based DAQ measurement syst.docx
3  If you like to develop a computer-based DAQ measurement syst.docx3  If you like to develop a computer-based DAQ measurement syst.docx
3 If you like to develop a computer-based DAQ measurement syst.docx
 
2BackgroundThe research focuses on investigating leaders fro.docx
2BackgroundThe research focuses on investigating leaders fro.docx2BackgroundThe research focuses on investigating leaders fro.docx
2BackgroundThe research focuses on investigating leaders fro.docx
 
2TITLE OF PAPERDavid B. JonesColumbia Southe.docx
2TITLE OF PAPERDavid B. JonesColumbia Southe.docx2TITLE OF PAPERDavid B. JonesColumbia Southe.docx
2TITLE OF PAPERDavid B. JonesColumbia Southe.docx
 
2To ADD names From ADD name Date ADD date Subject ADD ti.docx
2To  ADD names From  ADD name Date  ADD date Subject  ADD ti.docx2To  ADD names From  ADD name Date  ADD date Subject  ADD ti.docx
2To ADD names From ADD name Date ADD date Subject ADD ti.docx
 
2Megan Bowen02042020 Professor Cozen Comm 146Int.docx
2Megan Bowen02042020 Professor Cozen Comm 146Int.docx2Megan Bowen02042020 Professor Cozen Comm 146Int.docx
2Megan Bowen02042020 Professor Cozen Comm 146Int.docx
 
2From On the Advantage and Disadvantage of History for L.docx
2From On the Advantage and Disadvantage of History for L.docx2From On the Advantage and Disadvantage of History for L.docx
2From On the Advantage and Disadvantage of History for L.docx
 
28 jOURNAL Of MULTICULTURAL COUNSELING AND DEVELOpMENT • Janua.docx
28 jOURNAL Of MULTICULTURAL COUNSELING AND DEVELOpMENT • Janua.docx28 jOURNAL Of MULTICULTURAL COUNSELING AND DEVELOpMENT • Janua.docx
28 jOURNAL Of MULTICULTURAL COUNSELING AND DEVELOpMENT • Janua.docx
 
2Fifth Edition COMMUNITY PSYCHOLOGY.docx
2Fifth Edition   COMMUNITY PSYCHOLOGY.docx2Fifth Edition   COMMUNITY PSYCHOLOGY.docx
2Fifth Edition COMMUNITY PSYCHOLOGY.docx
 
257Speaking of researchGuidelines for evaluating resea.docx
257Speaking of researchGuidelines for evaluating resea.docx257Speaking of researchGuidelines for evaluating resea.docx
257Speaking of researchGuidelines for evaluating resea.docx
 
2800 word count.APA formatplagiarism free paperThe paper.docx
2800 word count.APA formatplagiarism free paperThe paper.docx2800 word count.APA formatplagiarism free paperThe paper.docx
2800 word count.APA formatplagiarism free paperThe paper.docx
 
28 CHAPTER 4 THE CARBON FOOTPRINT CONTROVERSY Wha.docx
28  CHAPTER 4 THE CARBON FOOTPRINT CONTROVERSY  Wha.docx28  CHAPTER 4 THE CARBON FOOTPRINT CONTROVERSY  Wha.docx
28 CHAPTER 4 THE CARBON FOOTPRINT CONTROVERSY Wha.docx
 
250 WORDS Moyer Instruments is a rapidly growing manufacturer .docx
250 WORDS Moyer Instruments is a rapidly growing manufacturer .docx250 WORDS Moyer Instruments is a rapidly growing manufacturer .docx
250 WORDS Moyer Instruments is a rapidly growing manufacturer .docx
 
250 WORDS CITATION AND REFERNECES What is a definition of fami.docx
250 WORDS CITATION AND REFERNECES What is a definition of fami.docx250 WORDS CITATION AND REFERNECES What is a definition of fami.docx
250 WORDS CITATION AND REFERNECES What is a definition of fami.docx
 

Recently uploaded

Capitol Tech U Doctoral Presentation - April 2024.pptx
Capitol Tech U Doctoral Presentation - April 2024.pptxCapitol Tech U Doctoral Presentation - April 2024.pptx
Capitol Tech U Doctoral Presentation - April 2024.pptxCapitolTechU
 
Roles & Responsibilities in Pharmacovigilance
Roles & Responsibilities in PharmacovigilanceRoles & Responsibilities in Pharmacovigilance
Roles & Responsibilities in PharmacovigilanceSamikshaHamane
 
Historical philosophical, theoretical, and legal foundations of special and i...
Historical philosophical, theoretical, and legal foundations of special and i...Historical philosophical, theoretical, and legal foundations of special and i...
Historical philosophical, theoretical, and legal foundations of special and i...jaredbarbolino94
 
ECONOMIC CONTEXT - LONG FORM TV DRAMA - PPT
ECONOMIC CONTEXT - LONG FORM TV DRAMA - PPTECONOMIC CONTEXT - LONG FORM TV DRAMA - PPT
ECONOMIC CONTEXT - LONG FORM TV DRAMA - PPTiammrhaywood
 
Biting mechanism of poisonous snakes.pdf
Biting mechanism of poisonous snakes.pdfBiting mechanism of poisonous snakes.pdf
Biting mechanism of poisonous snakes.pdfadityarao40181
 
CELL CYCLE Division Science 8 quarter IV.pptx
CELL CYCLE Division Science 8 quarter IV.pptxCELL CYCLE Division Science 8 quarter IV.pptx
CELL CYCLE Division Science 8 quarter IV.pptxJiesonDelaCerna
 
Introduction to ArtificiaI Intelligence in Higher Education
Introduction to ArtificiaI Intelligence in Higher EducationIntroduction to ArtificiaI Intelligence in Higher Education
Introduction to ArtificiaI Intelligence in Higher Educationpboyjonauth
 
Meghan Sutherland In Media Res Media Component
Meghan Sutherland In Media Res Media ComponentMeghan Sutherland In Media Res Media Component
Meghan Sutherland In Media Res Media ComponentInMediaRes1
 
Types of Journalistic Writing Grade 8.pptx
Types of Journalistic Writing Grade 8.pptxTypes of Journalistic Writing Grade 8.pptx
Types of Journalistic Writing Grade 8.pptxEyham Joco
 
How to Make a Pirate ship Primary Education.pptx
How to Make a Pirate ship Primary Education.pptxHow to Make a Pirate ship Primary Education.pptx
How to Make a Pirate ship Primary Education.pptxmanuelaromero2013
 
call girls in Kamla Market (DELHI) 🔝 >༒9953330565🔝 genuine Escort Service 🔝✔️✔️
call girls in Kamla Market (DELHI) 🔝 >༒9953330565🔝 genuine Escort Service 🔝✔️✔️call girls in Kamla Market (DELHI) 🔝 >༒9953330565🔝 genuine Escort Service 🔝✔️✔️
call girls in Kamla Market (DELHI) 🔝 >༒9953330565🔝 genuine Escort Service 🔝✔️✔️9953056974 Low Rate Call Girls In Saket, Delhi NCR
 
Interactive Powerpoint_How to Master effective communication
Interactive Powerpoint_How to Master effective communicationInteractive Powerpoint_How to Master effective communication
Interactive Powerpoint_How to Master effective communicationnomboosow
 
History Class XII Ch. 3 Kinship, Caste and Class (1).pptx
History Class XII Ch. 3 Kinship, Caste and Class (1).pptxHistory Class XII Ch. 3 Kinship, Caste and Class (1).pptx
History Class XII Ch. 3 Kinship, Caste and Class (1).pptxsocialsciencegdgrohi
 
MARGINALIZATION (Different learners in Marginalized Group
MARGINALIZATION (Different learners in Marginalized GroupMARGINALIZATION (Different learners in Marginalized Group
MARGINALIZATION (Different learners in Marginalized GroupJonathanParaisoCruz
 
Painted Grey Ware.pptx, PGW Culture of India
Painted Grey Ware.pptx, PGW Culture of IndiaPainted Grey Ware.pptx, PGW Culture of India
Painted Grey Ware.pptx, PGW Culture of IndiaVirag Sontakke
 
Hierarchy of management that covers different levels of management
Hierarchy of management that covers different levels of managementHierarchy of management that covers different levels of management
Hierarchy of management that covers different levels of managementmkooblal
 
Earth Day Presentation wow hello nice great
Earth Day Presentation wow hello nice greatEarth Day Presentation wow hello nice great
Earth Day Presentation wow hello nice greatYousafMalik24
 

Recently uploaded (20)

Model Call Girl in Bikash Puri Delhi reach out to us at 🔝9953056974🔝
Model Call Girl in Bikash Puri  Delhi reach out to us at 🔝9953056974🔝Model Call Girl in Bikash Puri  Delhi reach out to us at 🔝9953056974🔝
Model Call Girl in Bikash Puri Delhi reach out to us at 🔝9953056974🔝
 
Capitol Tech U Doctoral Presentation - April 2024.pptx
Capitol Tech U Doctoral Presentation - April 2024.pptxCapitol Tech U Doctoral Presentation - April 2024.pptx
Capitol Tech U Doctoral Presentation - April 2024.pptx
 
Roles & Responsibilities in Pharmacovigilance
Roles & Responsibilities in PharmacovigilanceRoles & Responsibilities in Pharmacovigilance
Roles & Responsibilities in Pharmacovigilance
 
Historical philosophical, theoretical, and legal foundations of special and i...
Historical philosophical, theoretical, and legal foundations of special and i...Historical philosophical, theoretical, and legal foundations of special and i...
Historical philosophical, theoretical, and legal foundations of special and i...
 
ECONOMIC CONTEXT - LONG FORM TV DRAMA - PPT
ECONOMIC CONTEXT - LONG FORM TV DRAMA - PPTECONOMIC CONTEXT - LONG FORM TV DRAMA - PPT
ECONOMIC CONTEXT - LONG FORM TV DRAMA - PPT
 
Biting mechanism of poisonous snakes.pdf
Biting mechanism of poisonous snakes.pdfBiting mechanism of poisonous snakes.pdf
Biting mechanism of poisonous snakes.pdf
 
CELL CYCLE Division Science 8 quarter IV.pptx
CELL CYCLE Division Science 8 quarter IV.pptxCELL CYCLE Division Science 8 quarter IV.pptx
CELL CYCLE Division Science 8 quarter IV.pptx
 
Introduction to ArtificiaI Intelligence in Higher Education
Introduction to ArtificiaI Intelligence in Higher EducationIntroduction to ArtificiaI Intelligence in Higher Education
Introduction to ArtificiaI Intelligence in Higher Education
 
9953330565 Low Rate Call Girls In Rohini Delhi NCR
9953330565 Low Rate Call Girls In Rohini  Delhi NCR9953330565 Low Rate Call Girls In Rohini  Delhi NCR
9953330565 Low Rate Call Girls In Rohini Delhi NCR
 
Meghan Sutherland In Media Res Media Component
Meghan Sutherland In Media Res Media ComponentMeghan Sutherland In Media Res Media Component
Meghan Sutherland In Media Res Media Component
 
Types of Journalistic Writing Grade 8.pptx
Types of Journalistic Writing Grade 8.pptxTypes of Journalistic Writing Grade 8.pptx
Types of Journalistic Writing Grade 8.pptx
 
How to Make a Pirate ship Primary Education.pptx
How to Make a Pirate ship Primary Education.pptxHow to Make a Pirate ship Primary Education.pptx
How to Make a Pirate ship Primary Education.pptx
 
call girls in Kamla Market (DELHI) 🔝 >༒9953330565🔝 genuine Escort Service 🔝✔️✔️
call girls in Kamla Market (DELHI) 🔝 >༒9953330565🔝 genuine Escort Service 🔝✔️✔️call girls in Kamla Market (DELHI) 🔝 >༒9953330565🔝 genuine Escort Service 🔝✔️✔️
call girls in Kamla Market (DELHI) 🔝 >༒9953330565🔝 genuine Escort Service 🔝✔️✔️
 
Interactive Powerpoint_How to Master effective communication
Interactive Powerpoint_How to Master effective communicationInteractive Powerpoint_How to Master effective communication
Interactive Powerpoint_How to Master effective communication
 
History Class XII Ch. 3 Kinship, Caste and Class (1).pptx
History Class XII Ch. 3 Kinship, Caste and Class (1).pptxHistory Class XII Ch. 3 Kinship, Caste and Class (1).pptx
History Class XII Ch. 3 Kinship, Caste and Class (1).pptx
 
MARGINALIZATION (Different learners in Marginalized Group
MARGINALIZATION (Different learners in Marginalized GroupMARGINALIZATION (Different learners in Marginalized Group
MARGINALIZATION (Different learners in Marginalized Group
 
Painted Grey Ware.pptx, PGW Culture of India
Painted Grey Ware.pptx, PGW Culture of IndiaPainted Grey Ware.pptx, PGW Culture of India
Painted Grey Ware.pptx, PGW Culture of India
 
Hierarchy of management that covers different levels of management
Hierarchy of management that covers different levels of managementHierarchy of management that covers different levels of management
Hierarchy of management that covers different levels of management
 
OS-operating systems- ch04 (Threads) ...
OS-operating systems- ch04 (Threads) ...OS-operating systems- ch04 (Threads) ...
OS-operating systems- ch04 (Threads) ...
 
Earth Day Presentation wow hello nice great
Earth Day Presentation wow hello nice greatEarth Day Presentation wow hello nice great
Earth Day Presentation wow hello nice great
 

261Megaregion Planningand High-Speed RailPetra Tod.docx

  • 1. 261 Megaregion Planning and High-Speed Rail Petra Todorovich c h a p t e r 2 4 ? On April 16, 2009, President Obama stood before an audience at the Eisenhower Executive Office Building and made an announcement that signaled a new era of passenger rail in the United States. Months before, the American Recovery and Reinvestment Act (ARRA) had provided $8 billion for a new program at the Federal Railroad Administration (FRA) to issue competitive grants to states to make capital investments in high-speed and conventional passenger rail. Little did the president know that providing the single largest boost for intercity rail plan- ning in this country in a generation had also motivated a sudden and giant leap for- ward in planning and governing megaregions. Luckily, regional planners had been studying emerging megaregions for the previous five years, in affiliation with the
  • 2. New York–based Regional Plan Association’s (RPA) America 2050 program. Again and again, the planners had identified high-speed rail as the key transportation investment to serve megaregion economies. But high-speed rail was a distant dream. That all changed with the passage of ARRA at the nadir of the Great Recession. Now a federal program exists to support high-speed rail planning and implementation. Making that program a success will largely depend on the ability of multiple actors at the local, regional, state, and binational levels to come together as megaregions to coordinate and leverage federal rail investments. Revisiting Megalopolis: RPA Resurrects the Megaregion Idea As if planning for the Tri-State New York metropolitan region was not sufficiently complicated, in 2005 the Regional Plan Association launched a national program called America 2050 that focused on the emergence of a new urban scale: the megaregion. This was not actually a new concept for RPA. In 1967 a volume of the Second Regional Plan documented the emergence of “The Atlantic Urban Region,” an urban chain stretching 460 miles from Maine to Virginia (Regional Plan C o p
  • 8. a b l e c o p y r i g h t l a w . EBSCO Publishing : eBook Academic Collection (EBSCOhost) - printed on 5/8/2020 3:56 AM via SAN JOSE STATE UNIV AN: 435124 ; Montgomery, Carleton.; Regional Planning for a Sustainable America : How Creative Programs Are Promoting Prosperity and Saving the Environment Account: s7380033.main.cmmc Association 1967). Earlier that decade, French geographer Jean Gottmann had coined the term “Megalopolis” to describe the same region in his 1961 book, Megalopolis: The Urbanized Northeastern Seaboard of the United States (Gottmann 1961). The Northeast’s more or less continuous urbanization
  • 9. from the northern suburbs of Boston to the southern suburbs of Washington, D.C., had attracted the attention of Gottmann and RPA. But in 1967 RPA observed that while this chain of settlements containing 42 million people surely derived some benefit from their mutual proximity, the larger form of the Atlantic Urban Region was still composed of more or less independent metropolitan regions. By 2005, when RPA revisited that larger form, the autonomy of the Northeast’s metropolitan regions was starting to wane. Rapid, low-density sprawl was erasing the formerly distinct boundaries between the New York and Philadelphia metro- politan regions, and between Philadelphia and Wilmington. The term “extreme commutes” had been coined by the U.S. Census to describe road warriors traveling more than ninety minutes each way to their jobs, with many of them located in the Northeast. And intercity business travel within the Northeast was also growing. The four most congested airports in the country were located in New York City, Newark, and Philadelphia. With 251 daily flights taking place among the Northeast’s major airports, and 40 percent of Amtrak’s rail ridership taking place on the Northeast Corridor, a Northeast Megaregion was moving from a spatial construct to reality (RPA 2007). But at the dawn of the twenty-first century, the forces making
  • 10. the Northeast Megaregion a more cohesive and integrated megaregion were also threatening its demise. Growing congestion in its roads, rail network, and airports; rising house costs; loss of open space; and threats to clean drinking water all contributed to imperil the Northeast’s future as an economic competitor and healthy and pleas- ant place to live. In other words, the Northeast was (and is) heading toward the dystopian vision of Megalopolis—a region of continuous sprawl with infrastruc- ture systems that are too crowded and too deteriorated to function efficiently, a high cost of living, and a natural environment that has suffered the impacts of an aggressive human footprint. As Regional Plan Association’s president, Robert Yaro, frequently remarks, “The Northeast has all the disadvantages of being the most expensive, densely populated, and congested region in the country—and none of the advantages.” The subtext of this statement is that we need to flip the equation around and capture the benefits of having the most population density, the most expansive rail transit network, and the largest concentration of skilled workers in the nation. To do so, RPA set out to understand the larger phenomenon of megaregions and how they were playing out around the country. Scaling Up: America’s Emerging Megaregions
  • 11. In 2004 Robert Yaro, Armando Carbonell, and Jonathan Barnett led a graduate planning studio at the University of Pennsylvania called Plan for America. The Plan for America studio traveled to Europe on spring break to meet with Sir Peter Hall at s o c i e t y , e c o n o m i c s a n d p l a n n i n g262 EBSCOhost - printed on 5/8/2020 3:56 AM via SAN JOSE STATE UNIV. All use subject to https://www.ebsco.com/terms- of-use University College London, where students and professors alike were inspired by the European Spatial Development Perspective (ESDP), a 1999 policy statement on balanced growth in the European territory. The imaginative spatial planners behind the ESDP had identified large urban agglomerations in Central Europe like the Pentagon and the Blue Banana (Faludi 2002). Also called “global integration zones,” these networked cities and regions in the EU were supported by open border policies among EU member states and strengthened by EU investments in the Trans-European Network and high-speed passenger rail. Adopting a similar spatial perspective on urban networks in America, the Penn students identified a series of possible “supercities,” which were later redefined by RPA as megaregions.
  • 12. RPA launched its America 2050 program after the Penn students issued their final report in spring 2004. The RPA prospectus on America 2050 outlined the case for adopting a megaregion perspective and national plan (RPA 2006). Generally, it argued that five major trends shaping the United States demanded a national plan- ning and infrastructure strategy for accommodating future growth. They included the following: • America’s rapid population growth, about 130 million additional people by 2050 • Overburdened and deteriorating infrastructure systems • The urgent need to mitigate climate change and reduce our dependence on fossil fuels and oil imports • Growing social and economic disparities within and between regions • And the emergence of a new urban form: megaregions Megaregions are networks of proximate metropolitan regions, connected by transportation systems, natural systems, settlement patterns, and linked economies. Eleven emerging U.S. megaregions capture over 70 percent of the nation’s population and jobs (see fig. 24.1). They present a new scale at which to plan and coordinate large infrastructure and natural systems—a scale at which there are few examples of governance models, let alone institutions capable of planning or financing complex systems like high-speed rail.
  • 13. Given this vacuum, America 2050 set out to address a planning void at two different scales: federal, where leadership would surely be required to help plan, finance, and facilitate partnerships needed to meet the challenges described here; and the megaregion, by conducting research, building coalitions, and identifying best practices for megaregion planning and coordination. The first several years of the America 2050 program were spent building a base of research to underpin our understanding of megaregions and verify that this urban form was present outside the Northeast. All of the research that America 2050 assembled is located permanently on the America 2050 website in its research section. During this time, RPA began to think about megaregions as organized around specific relationships that present themselves at the larger scale—such as water resources in the Great Lakes Megaregion, intercity rail in the Northeast Corridor, a common coastline and vulnerability to natural and man-made disasters in the Gulf Coast, seaport and goods movement issues in southern f i n d i n g a c a t a l y s t i n h i g h - s p e e d r a i l 263 EBSCOhost - printed on 5/8/2020 3:56 AM via SAN JOSE STATE UNIV. All use subject to https://www.ebsco.com/terms- of-use
  • 15. e U n it ed S ta te s EBSCOhost - printed on 5/8/2020 3:56 AM via SAN JOSE STATE UNIV. All use subject to https://www.ebsco.com/terms- of-use California, and urban sprawl in northern California. Recognizing these critical relationships was the key to unlocking interest by regional stakeholders in cooper- ating with each other. “You’re in a megaregion; do something about it” was not a compelling opening line. However, they found that “working with your neighbors is critical to solving fill-in-the-blank” elicited much more interest. From 2005 to 2008, megaregion studies were conducted in eight megaregions, mostly at or in partnership with graduate planning schools, including University of Pennsylvania, Georgia Tech, Portland State University, Arizona
  • 16. State University, University of Michigan, and University of Texas at Austin. In addition, several councils of governments in California (Sacramento Area Council of Governments, San Diego Association of Governments, and Kern County) published a study of the Southwest Megaregion, which led to their continued cooperation on goods movement and airport planning. In Florida, the South Florida Regional Planning Council prepared a study of the Florida Megaregion and convened a conference around it in 2006. In northern California, the independent planning and civic organization SPUR published a study of the Northern California Megaregion, stretching from the Bay Area to Sacramento. Following the SPUR study, trans- portation officials from across the megaregion came together to submit a joint application for a northern California freight program that was successful in secur- ing $840 million from the California Transportation Commission, an achievement they regarded as a “coup” (Nelson 2008). Rail Advocacy in the Northeast Corridor Back in the Northeast Megaregion, RPA helped revive a coalition of business groups that had previously advocated for Amtrak funding to form the Business Alliance for Northeast Mobility. With a reinvigorated membership of about thirty chambers of commerce and civic organizations from Maine to Virginia, the
  • 17. Business Alliance began lobbying Congress in 2006 for increased rail funding to bring Amtrak’s Northeast Rail Corridor to a state of good repair. The Business Alliance focused on turning one of the key disadvantages of the Northeast’s geography—fragmented governance among twelve states—into a political advantage— twenty-four U.S. senators and dozens more U.S. representatives. The Business Alliance held several rail advocacy events at the U.S. Capitol and at Union Station in Washington, D.C., in 2007–2008 with members of the Northeast Delegation. The strategy seemed to work. In 2008, after previous unsuccessful attempts, Congress passed the Passenger Rail Investment Improvement Act, which authorized approximately $13 billion in funding for Amtrak over five years and set up a new High Speed Intercity Passenger Rail program at the Federal Railroad Administration that provided competitive grants to states to invest in capital improvements for passenger rail. This new program was put to use immediately, by serving as the legislative vehicle for the $8 billion appropriation of high-speed rail funding in ARRA. The subsequent year, federal appropriators reaffirmed their commitment to the high- speed rail program with another $2.5 billion for the high-speed program. f i n d i n g a c a t a l y s t i n h i g h - s p e e d r a i l 265 EBSCOhost - printed on 5/8/2020 3:56 AM via SAN JOSE
  • 18. STATE UNIV. All use subject to https://www.ebsco.com/terms- of-use With painful irony, a relatively small share of the money made its way to the Northeast Corridor. The Business Alliance had gambled on advocating for increased national rail funding, because about half of Amtrak’s annual capital investments are typically made in the Northeast Corridor, Amtrak’s largest rail infrastructure asset. And, indeed, approximately $706 million included in ARRA for Amtrak came to the Northeast Corridor in 2009, along with additional funding in the 2010 annual appropriation (Federal Railroad Administration 2010). But little of the $8 billion in high-speed rail grants came to the Northeast Corridor, for two frustratingly technical reasons. None of Amtrak’s Northeast Corridor projects could be completed in two years—a statutory requirement of the stimulus bill— and the Northeast Corridor states had recently initiated a master planning process for 2030, which had triggered the need for a new, corridor-wide environmental impact statement (EIS). All of the high-speed rail grants from the stimulus bill required a completed EIS, and the Northeast Corridor’s had yet to begin and would certainly take a minimum of two years. So after playing a role in securing rail funding for the entire country, the Northeast Corridor sat on
  • 19. the sidelines as the largest passenger rail grants in decades were doled out in California, Florida, the Midwest, and other regions. On the bright side, being passed over seems to have acted as a wake-up call to transportation officials in the Northeast states, who have reemerged with greater motivation to better coordinate in the future for federal funding. In June 2010, eleven Northeast states submitted an application to the FRA for $18.8 million in planning funds to conduct a comprehensive planning study for the Northeast Corridor, building on the master plan. The new planning study would allow Northeast states to break out individual capital projects on the corridor with independent utility that could be funded through the federal high-speed rail program and complete the required EIS for the corridor for a doubling of ridership by 2030. Of most interest to this author, the planning study and EIS would also consider a true high-speed rail option of building two new dedicated tracks along the Northeast Corridor for high-speed trains, significantly increasing capacity and reducing trip times on the corridor—and competing with the other world-class high-speed rail systems being planned in California and Florida. Such an outcome could be the key to realizing the promise of an integrated Northeast Megaregion economy and act as the ultimate test for megaregion
  • 20. cooperation. Megaregions and High-Speed Rail High-speed rail is not just a test for megaregion coordination; it also promises great reward. In fact, it is likely that only with the fast and convenient ground connections provided by high-speed rail can megaregions realize the productivity benefits of their metropolitan economies acting as integrated units. This is the difference between the Northeast Megaregion’s dystopian future and the desired path. High-speed rail could act as the main intercity transportation spine for an expanded megaregion-scale rail transit network, enhanced with transit oriented s o c i e t y , e c o n o m i c s a n d p l a n n i n g266 EBSCOhost - printed on 5/8/2020 3:56 AM via SAN JOSE STATE UNIV. All use subject to https://www.ebsco.com/terms- of-use development. A Northeast megaregion (and other megaregions) linked by high- speed rail could potentially realize the following benefits: • Increased productivity for service-based businesses gained by time savings and increased mobility. Faster, more frequent, and reliable connections that enable business trips among the specialized economies of the
  • 21. Northeast (i.e., education and health services in Boston; financial services and media in New York; government and professional services in Washington) can foster greater productivity for the megaregion as a whole. • Expanding the scope of labor markets accessed by major employment centers. Faster rail connections between employment hubs and adjacent, smaller cities and residential areas can deepen labor markets, giving employers access to more workers and providing workers with more and cheaper housing options (Martin Prosperity Insight 2010). • Bringing smaller and underperforming cities within two-hour commuting distance of major employment hubs (like Boston, New York, and Washington) can potentially benefit cities like Hartford, Worcester, and Philadelphia, which have been losing jobs steadily in recent decades. This could also take pressure off the housing market in larger cities, if workers can work in New York and live in Philadelphia, for example (Regional Plan Association 2007). • Focusing development and real estate opportunities around stations. Rail passenger stations provide focal points for transportation- oriented development, such as new office, retail, institutional, and
  • 22. residential development. Focusing development around transportation hubs can reduce the need to drive, enliven and activate communities, and promote energy savings through transportation and building related efficiencies. Regional planning must recognize and capitalize on the self- interest of local actors that make up a region in order to be successful. Megaregion planning is no different in its need to tap into the mutual self-interest of component metropolitan actors. Yet megaregion planning is even more difficult than regional planning because the megaregion scale is less connected to individuals’ daily experiences than the metropolitan region. In light of these challenges, America 2050 has found that megaregion cooperation must be motivated by the promise of clear and tangible rewards to be gained by megaregion cooperation. Such rewards, in the form of federal high-speed rail planning grants, have recently brought megaregions together to develop corridor-wide rail plans and explore governance models for finance, construction, and rail service operations. These regions, particularly those that span multiple states and international boundaries, will need to establish formal partnerships to manage major procedures like procurement and financing. The greater promise of high-speed rail—increased productivity, access to larger job markets, promoting sustainable land development,
  • 23. and revitalizing cities—will require a broader regional planning perspective at the megaregion scale. In this way, high speed is providing a laboratory for megaregion planning. f i n d i n g a c a t a l y s t i n h i g h - s p e e d r a i l 267 EBSCOhost - printed on 5/8/2020 3:56 AM via SAN JOSE STATE UNIV. All use subject to https://www.ebsco.com/terms- of-use WPC 480. Week 8 1 For next week… Complete Case Paper #3 on Aldi Due at our next class March 19th Focused on Cost Leadership and Differentiation Strategies. NO Blue Ocean! NO Business Models Focus on Chapter (After tonight – it’s Spring Break) 2 Generic Business Strategies
  • 24. Differentiation Seeks to create higher value than competitors Offers products or services with unique features Keeps the firm’s cost structure as low as possible Charges higher prices Cost Leadership Seeks to create similar value as competitors Products or services delivered at lower cost Charges lower prices Business-level Strategies Cost leadership
  • 25. Sources of keeping costs down and prices low Cost of input factors (supplier power matters here) Economies of scale Employing specialized systems and equipment Minimum efficient scale – increases in volume do not lead to further cost reductions Implies large market share almost always to get the best economies of scale 8 Cost leadership: It takes time to reduce costs Learning Curve Effects – price drops (and quality increases) as volume increases over time Versus Economy of Scales: Economy of Scales are a specific points in time versus accumulation over time Differences in Complexity: Depending on product/service EoS may have stronger impacts than learning curves Experience Curve Effects – price drops (and quality increases) with changes in technology of production Process Innovation: changes in technology allow increased efficiency with same output volume. Technology can be changes in methods or machinery 9 Attributes of the Product/Service offering Relationships between company and consumers Linkages within or between firms
  • 26. Differentiation Strategy Blue Ocean Strategy Value Innovation: Aligning consumer utility, price and cost for maximizing value to company and consumer – product differentiation and low cost. 8 Blue Ocean Strategy Strategy Canvas: Captures current state of the known market place and action framework to explore alternatives. 9 Blue Ocean Strategy 4 Action Framework: To assist in creating a new value curve the 4 Action Framework helps evaluate the tradeoffs between differentiation and cost.
  • 27. 10 Blue Ocean Strategy 11 Blue Ocean Shift 12 Activity In your group, identify a company who has a Blue Ocean strategy Identify that BO company’s competitors or industry Identify the factors that consumers use to make decisions about their purchases with this company. What factors were raised/created by the BO company or eliminated/decreased? 13 Risks of Blue Ocean Finding the right blue ocean – easy to say but hard to find/create Arriving too early and/or Being too new, too different – are consumers ready? Strategy Execution – Right leaders? Strategic Clarity and Mindset – ready for the challenges from top to bottom Trust and Patience
  • 28. How defensible is your new ocean? 14 Blue Ocean vs. Yoda 15 Tradeoffs Maintain a focus on the consumer Who won’t buy the products/services, or which potentially profitable consumers are ignored or avoided? Mutually exclusive choices to commit resources Tradeoffs give something up – they “hurt” Resource commitments other firms cannot easily match Questions for you as an analyst Sufficient consistency in tradeoffs over time? Inconsistency creates a “stuck in the middle” situation where the firm is not great at any one thing Strategic discipline to avoid being “stuck in the middle” No firm starts wanting to be stuck in the middle Discipline over time required to be true to tradeoffs How do these threaten discipline in tradeoffs? Customers Employees Management Shareholders
  • 29. Technology The Conundrum 18 Drew Houston, Founder of DropBox Attributes of the Product/Service offering Features, Complexity/Simplicity, Location Relationships between company and consumers Customization, Marketing, Brand, Services Linkages within or between firms Enhancing connections to other parts of a business or to another business Complement – consuming in tandem Networks Differentiation Strategy 2018 US best sellers by volume 1. Ford F Series 909K 2. Chevy Silverado 586K 3. Ram Pickup 537K 4. Toyota RAV4 427K 5. Nissan Rogue 412K How are they differentiated? 6. Honda CR-V 379K 7. Toyota Camry 343K
  • 30. 8. Chevy Equinox 333K https://www.automobilemag.com/news/year-auto-sales-facts- figures-bestsellers-2018/ https://www.caranddriver.com/news/g25558401/best-selling- cars-suv-trucks-2018/?slide=25 20 Problem of sustaining: What won’t we do? US$211,000 Lamborghini Urus US$33,000 Nissan Rogue Sport US$130,000 Porsche Cayenne US$171,000 Maserati Levante US$40,000 Volkswagen Tiguan US$46,000 Mazda CX-9 Activity Breaking into groups Consider ASU and its competitors How is ASU Differentiated?
  • 31. How is W. P. Carey Differentiated? What factors would you highlight for each of the above? 22 Managerial levers to differentiate a firm strategically Clear goal for strategy (the constant checklist) Who? What will we satisfy? Why do we want to do this? How we will do this? Levers to differentiate Product features (blurs w/marketing) Customer service (blurs w/operations here) Complements (blurs w/industry boundaries AND competitors) Example: Disney World, Sea World, Universal Studios and Orlando air flights Networks effects, or why not to buy a Fiat in the U.S. What is meaningful about being a differentiator? How does this strategy motivate people by making them feel meaningful? How do you know you have made progress and improvement as a differentiator? What are reasons employees might enjoy being a differentiator? Differentiation Strategy Product Characteristics
  • 32. Unique, special, premium High service, new product launches Acceptable price Goal Increase perception of value Capture perception with higher prices Resources are focused on Creating higher value Marketing & Promotion Innovation/ Exploration Differentiation Response to Five Forces Threat of Rivalry
  • 33. customer’s brand loyalty to differentiated product offsets price competition Power of Buyers well differentiated products reduce customer sensitivity to price increases Power of Suppliers absorb price increases due to higher margins pass along higher supplier prices due to buyer loyalty Differentiation Response to Five Forces Threat of New Entrants differentiation sets a high bar on performance and brand Threat of Substitutes brand loyalty to a differentiated product tends to reduce customers’ testing of new products or switching brands
  • 34. Competitive Risks of Differentiation The price differential between the differentiator’s product and the cost leader’s product becomes too large Differentiation ceases to provide value for which customers are willing to pay Experience narrows customers’ perceptions of the value of differentiated features Counterfeit goods replicate the differentiated features of the firm’s products For next week… Complete Case Paper #3 on Aldi Due at our next class March 19th Focused on Cost Leadership and Differentiation Strategies. NO Blue Ocean! NO Business Models Focus on Chapter 6
  • 35. (After tonight – 0 class till Spring Break) 29 WPC 480. Week 10 1 Upcoming Assignments Quiz 5 – Chapter 8 March 26th - Due today Quiz 6 – Chapter 9 April 2nd Quiz 7 – Chapter 12 April 9th SAS Paper #4 – April 16th Quiz 8 – Chapter 10 April 23rd Group Analysis Paper – April 23rd Exec Interview Presentation – April 30th Final Exam – May 7th Thursday 6 PM to 7:50 PM 2 For next week… Topic: Corporate Strategy: Mergers & Acquisitions… Textbook Reading: Chapter 9 Quiz #6 over Chapter 9 due April 2nd Need volunteer for Chapter 9 mini-case presentation on Lyft.
  • 36. (After tonight – 6 classes till end of semester) 3 Growth 4 Growth Options Diversification – Increase in variety Vertical Integration – Forward or Backward on value chain 5 Industry 1 Diversification Industry 2 Vertical Integration Diversification 6
  • 37. 7 8 Related Diversification Firms create value by building upon or extending: resources capabilities core competencies Economies of Scope Cost savings that occur when a firm transfers capabilities and competencies developed in one of its businesses to another of its businesses
  • 38. Economies of Scope Operational EoS: Shared activities or leveraging core competencies or transferring skills among units Financial EoS: Internal capital markets – moving capital between units. (The only EoS that unrelated diversification can accomplish) Honda 11 Manufacturing Platforms Innovation Activities Shared Activities Lightweight, reliable engines Realized as Diversification Stand alone Marine Vehicles Yard Care Generators Boats Watercraft Cars, SUV, Vans Lawn mowers Snow Blowers Core Products Building Core Competencies Firms can diversify to build new competencies to transform the corporation
  • 39. 12 Restructuring Guide to Structure: Growth/Share Matrix Different investment strategies 13 Firm Performance 14 Vertical Intregation 15 Growth Options Diversification – Increase in variety Vertical Integration – Forward or Backward on value chain 16 Industry 1 Diversification
  • 40. Industry 2 Vertical Integration Vertical Integration 17 Make or Buy? When firms are more efficient than the market then consider vertical integration 18 Transaction Costs External transaction costs Searching for a firm or individual with which to contract Negotiating, monitoring, supervising and enforcing the contract Internal transaction costs Recruiting and retaining employees
  • 41. Paying salaries and benefits Setting up a shop floor Providing office space and computers, etc. Risk of Opportunisum: greatest with asset specificity problems Make or Buy? 20 $4.80 Foods (Mozzarella Cheese) Where your pizza comes from Dairy Farmers (milk) Crop Farmers (Alfalfa & Corn) Seed Companies (Alfalfa & Corn) Food Distributors
  • 42. Pizza Chains End Consumer Value Chain 21 $4.80 Foods (Mozzarella Cheese) Dairy Farmers (milk) Crop Farmers (Alfalfa & Corn) Seed Companies (Alfalfa & Corn) Food Distributors
  • 43. Pizza Chains End Consumer Backward Vertical Integration Forward Vertical Integration Vertical Integration 22 Activity Determine how diversified your company is per the matrix? How have they diversified? Have they vertically integrated? From what starting point and in what direction? Selected Companies 24
  • 44. Value Creation vs Costs 25 26 WPC 480. Week 7 1 For next week… Topic: Differentiation & Niches based on readings below… Textbook Reading: Chapter 6, Chapter 5 (pgs 165 – 171) Submit an article on a corporate merger or acquisition that’s not completed yet if you haven’t. (After tonight – 1 class till Spring Break) 2
  • 45. Team Presentation Strategy Mission: A firm’s long term purpose – what it aspires to be and what it will avoid in the meantime. Objectives: Specific measurable targets a firm can use to evaluate the extent to which it is realizing its mission. Strategy What is strategy? Your strategy is your theory of how to excel at the game you are playing A firm’s strategy is its theory of how to achieve high levels of performance in the markets and industries within which it is operating. Strategy is a position: Combine resources & capabilities that ‘position’ your firm in the industry Different positions in the industry are subject to distinct 5- forces Generic strategies: Differentiation – design strategies with core competencies to increase willingness to pay for target customers more than it increase costs for the firm Cost-leadership – design strategies with core competencies to lower costs for the firm by more than it decreases willingness to
  • 46. pay for target customers Strategy Blue Ocean Strategy 7 Blue Ocean Strategy Value Innovation: Aligning consumer utility, price and cost for maximizing value to company and consumer – product differentiation and low cost. 8 Business-level Strategies Customer Focus Key Issues in Business-level Strategy Who will be served?
  • 47. What needs will be satisfied? How will those needs be satisfied? Tradeoffs (stop imitators) Triad necessary for successful strategy Strong Positioning (competitive strategy) creates guides for making tradeoffs and creating organizations that fit Consistent tradeoffs create an organization that fits a competitive strategy and helps create barriers to competition Fit creates capabilities and resources that can be a guide to creating a strategy and making tradeoffs. Positioning (vs competitors) Fit (inside & outside) The Triad Cost leadership Confusing name – it really is about having the lowest price in your industry Generally low price requires lowest costs everywhere, but lowest prices are relative to competitors (so could be high absolute costs in some cases) Sources of keeping costs down and prices low Cost of input factors (supplier power matters here) Economies of scale Employing specialized systems and equipment Minimum efficient scale – increases in volume do not lead to
  • 48. further cost reductions Implies large market share almost always to get the best economies of scale 8 Cost leadership: It takes time to reduce costs Learning Curve Effects – price drops (and quality increases) as volume increases over time Versus Economy of Scales: Economy of Scales are a specific points in time versus accumulation over time Differences in Complexity: Depending on product/service EoS may have stronger impacts than learning curves Experience Curve Effects – price drops (and quality increases) with changes in technology of production Process Innovation: changes in technology allow increased efficiency with same output volume. Technology can be changes in methods or machinery 9 Cost leadership: It takes time to reduce costs Cost Leadership requires optimization of value chain overall, not just single steps Supplier/buyer relationships matter May increase costs in one step to lower them overall Ex: a costly automated packaging line lowers costs when demand is variable/grows Cost reductions must not threaten to impact product or service quality – they should increase or maintain quality 9
  • 49. Cost leadership: Discipline in managing growth Growth can cause diseconomies of scale also Example: increasing layers of hierarchy as firm grows if it doesn’t decentralize Success does not, generally, lead to people being “tighter” with money Have to fight the impulse to start adding extra costs because doing well Success can lead to a sense of higher status which can lead to increased spending to match new status Discipline includes unchanging rules about what to NOT to do Example: never increase profits when costs go down; keep margins the same Prohibitions on specific actions are easier to follow and communicate than abstract goals 10 Cost Leadership: Requires a culture of discipline and long view of time Needs to be a value everyone agrees upon to keep prices and costs low Continuous improvement only comes from a long-term commitment Top management has to keep focus to avoid growth traps and getting “stuck in the middle”
  • 50. 11 Cost Leadership Strategy Product Characteristics Relatively standardized (commoditized) products Features broadly acceptable to many customers Lowest competitive price Goal Reduce the firm’s cost below its competitors Offer adequate value Resources are focused on Reducing cost/ exploiting efficiencies
  • 51. Reducing prices for customers Activity 18 Create a 2x2 with the company and the competitors – Value on one axis and your choice on the other axis Tell us the factors aligned with the Cost Leadership Strategy. Supported with examples with activities, resources or capabilities How did they build or acquire these? 19 Activity Auto Industry – Hynduai, Kia Hotels – MicroTel, Motel 6 Mattresses – Casper, Tuft&Needle Real Estate Listings – Redfin Car Care – JiffyLube Personal Care Products – Razors
  • 52. Car Rentals – Budget 20 Cost Response to Five Forces Threat of Rivalry rivals hesitate to compete on basis of price lack of price competition leads to greater profits Power of Buyers drives prices far below competitors, causing them to exit, thus shifting power with buyers (customers) back to the firm increase switching costs Power of Suppliers able to absorb cost increases due to low cost position. able to make very large purchases, reducing chance of supplier using power
  • 53. Cost Response to Five Forces Threat of New Entrants enter on a large scale in order to be cost competitive increase the time it takes to move down the industry learning curve Threat of Substitutes lower prices in order to maintain its value position make investments to add features unavailable in substitutes Risks of Cost Leadership Strategy Processes used may become obsolete Erosion of Margins Competitors catch up and erode cost leader’s advantage
  • 54. Competitors shift consumer focus to non-price attributes Competitors, using their own core competencies, may successfully imitate the cost leader’s strategy Cost reductions may occur at expense of customers’ perceptions of value (cheap) 07-042 July 25, 2007 This case was prepared by Professor Rebecca M. Henderson, Joel Conkling and Scott Roberts. Professor Henderson is the Eastman Kodak Leaders for Manufacturing Professor of Management Copyright © 2007, Rebecca M. Henderson. This work is licensed under the Creative Commons Attribution- Noncommercial-No Derivative Works 3.0 Unported License. To view a copy of this license visit http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by-nc-nd/3.0/ or send a letter to Creative Commons, 171 Second Street, Suite 300, San Francisco, California, 94105, USA. SunPower: Focused on the Future of Solar Power Rebecca M. Henderson, Joel Conkling and Scott Roberts
  • 55. It was December 2006. Tom Werner, CEO of SunPower, glanced down at his watch and shook his head in dismay. His run was not going well, despite the sounds of John Lee Hooker’s “Boogie Chillen” coming through his earphones. He blamed the board meeting later that afternoon. Given SunPower’s position as the producer of the world’s most efficient solar cells, also known as photovoltaics or PV, and recent forecasts that solar power might be on the edge of explosive growth, he knew that he’d be asked some tough questions. Werner wondered how fast the solar power industry was likely to grow and how long SunPower’s advantage was likely to last. How could SunPower compete with much larger companies like Sharp and Q-Cells? Or with the niche “technology play” firms that were springing up? How could SunPower’s current advantage be turned into an enduring competitive edge? As the sun began to rise, Werner picked up the pace again, and began jogging home. Environmental Issues One of the most important drivers of the world’s renewed interest in solar power was its ability to offer energy independence in combination with significant environmental benefits. After all, the earth received more energy from the sun than humans consumed throughout an entire year. Since the burning of fossil fuels generated a number of noxious
  • 56. substances including SO2, NO, NO2, and particulates, concerns for human and environmental health had driven interest in solar power from its earliest days. But evidence that rising concentrations of CO2 in the earth’s atmosphere could pose large long-term environmental risks had significantly increased interest in the technology. SUNPOWER: FOCUSED ON THE FUTURE OF SOLAR POWER Rebecca M. Henderson, Joel Conkling and Scott Roberts July 25, 2007 2 For over a century, scientists had observed the “greenhouse effect,” the warming of the earth caused by the atmosphere’s increased absorption of infrared radiation resulting from increased concentrations of CO2 and other greenhouse gases in the atmosphere. Levels of CO2 had risen from around 280 parts per million volume (ppmv) before the industrial revolution to 380ppmv in 2006 higher than at any point in more than half a million years. Data presented in the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change’s (IPCC) 4th Assessment Report, a 6- year study on global warming involving 2,500 leading scientists from 100 countries, provided even more alarming statistics. For example: • Greenhouse gases rose 70% between 1970 and 2004 (28.7 to 49 billion tones per year in carbon dioxide).
  • 57. • CO2, which accounted for more than 75% of emissions, increased by 80% between 1970 and 2004. • Developed countries while accounting for 20% of the global population, contributed 46% of global greenhouse gas emissions. • Greenhouse gases were projected to increase between 20% and 90% by 2030 unless significant changes in global energy policies were made. Looking longer-term, many studies suggested that increasing concentrations of green house gases greatly increased the odds of catastrophic climate change. One study published in the journal Nature predicted that temperature increases of 3.24–3.6°F and CO2 increases to 500–550 ppmv would result in the extinction of 1,000,000 terrestrial species (25% of all land animals and plants) by 2050.1 Meanwhile, average global temperatures had already risen 1.33°F since 1906—and polar temperatures were rising faster still. Most scientists believed that the stabilization of CO2 levels was urgently required, but just what concentration constituted a “sustainable” CO2 level was a matter of some uncertainty. The IPCC report suggested three scenarios (Table A) for emission stabilization by 2030 and the impact such cuts would have on global warming and world GDP growth. Table A Stabilization Scenarios Emission Output Rise in Global
  • 58. Warming Cost to Annual GDP Growth in 2030 Scenario A 445-535 parts per million (ppm) 3.6 - 5.0°F 0.12% Scenario B 535-590 ppm 5.0 - 5.8°F 0.1% Scenario C 590-710 ppm 5.8 - 7.2°F 0.06% 31 Marinez Ferreira de Siqueira, Alan Grainger, et al., “Extinction Risk from Climate Change,” Nature, January 8, 2004, 427, p. 145-148. SUNPOWER: FOCUSED ON THE FUTURE OF SOLAR POWER Rebecca M. Henderson, Joel Conkling and Scott Roberts July 25, 2007 3 Scenario A, involving the most aggressive action, would result in a 3% cumulative cost to annual world GDP growth by 2030. At 2006 growth rates, however, global concentrations would reach 800 ppmv by the end of the 21st century. A sense of urgency about global warming had prompted many countries to search for aggressive, coordinated strategies to reduce CO2 emissions. (Table B gives CO2 emissions for electricity production by fuel type.) The most far-reaching attempt, the
  • 59. Kyoto Protocol, committed a number of countries to modest CO2 reductions by a 2012 deadline. As part of this “emission cap” approach, some signatories allocated CO2 emissions allowances to individual firms. The Kyoto Protocol permitted these allowances to be traded across borders, creating a “carbon market.” For example, a Spanish factory might find it profitable to reduce its emissions by a given amount and sell the allowances to another factory in Italy that planned to exceed its own quota. Even signatories that had not committed to emissions cuts could participate. These countries—mainly large developing countries such as China and India—could forgo emissions and sell them as credits to customers in other countries. Table B CO2 Emissions for Electricity Production Generation Type Tons CO2 per MWh Nuclear 0 Hydro power 0 Coal 0.999 Oil 0.942 Gas 0.439 Geothermal, Solar, Tide, Wave, Ocean, Wind, Waste and other 0 Source: CANMET Energy Technologie Centre 2 The advent of carbon trading in Europe had generated a large market. In the first half of 2006, over US$15 billion worth of carbon emissions were traded, five times more than the amount the year
  • 60. before,3 and CO2 trading schemes in the United States were being developed at the state level. As of 2006, renewable sources provided 13% of the world’s energy needs,4 while photovoltaic systems provided a mere .04% of the world’s electricity. The U.S. Department of Energy estimated that the country could supply its entire energy needs by covering .5% of its land area with solar cells.5 2 Cited in B. Gaiddon, M. Jedliczka, Environmental Benefits of PV Systems in OECD Cities, September 2006. 3 Economist, “Selling Hot Air”, September 7, 2006. 4 “Sunlit Uplands,” The Economist, June 2, 2007. 5 “Sunlit Uplands,” The Economist, June 2, 2007. SUNPOWER: FOCUSED ON THE FUTURE OF SOLAR POWER Rebecca M. Henderson, Joel Conkling and Scott Roberts July 25, 2007 4 Solar Power Industry Solar cell, or photovoltaic (PV) systems converted energy from the sun into electric current. Solar cell performance was measured in terms of conversion efficiency, the proportion of solar energy converted to electricity. The first commercial solar cells were introduced in the 1950s by Bell Labs, and had efficiencies below 4%.6 In 2006, PV efficiencies ranged from 10%-20% and some scientists
  • 61. believed that further research, combined with advances in installation methods, could push conversion efficiencies well over 20%, with 50% seen as the long-term “holy grail.”7 A typical solar cell produced about 0.5V — roughly one-third of a regular AA battery, far too small to be of any practical use by itself — and cells were thus combined in larger blocks, called modules. Although modules varied in size, they typically included 72 cells, and yielded between 30-45V. Once constructed, modules were typically combined in arrays or panels which were then integrated with “inverters” – sophisticated devices that converted the DC power output of the solar panels or arrays into the AC power used in conventional electrical appliances. While solar power was two to three times as expensive as the retail cost of electricity,8 the market continued to grow at a steep upward trajectory. As Figure 1 shows, module manufacturing began to ramp up a few years after module prices hit a plateau. (Exhibit 1 provides yearly production and price data spanning 1975 to 2005.) Solar photovoltaic power grew an average of 41% each year between 2003 and 2006,9 and was expected to grow 40% annually through 2011. Industry profits were expected to top $7.7 billion in 2007 and $11.5 billion by 2011.10 Roughly $1.7 billion in private equity and venture capital funds went into the industry in 2006 and another $4.5 billion was invested in publicly traded solar companies, most of it going toward expanding manufacturing capacity.11
  • 62. 6 http://www.nrel.gov/learning/re_photovoltaics.html 7 Vaclav Smil, 2003. Energy at the Crossroads, Cambridge: MIT Press, p. 288. 8 “Bright Prospects,” The Economist, March 8, 2007. 9 “Sunlit Uplands,” The Economist, June 2, 2007. 10 Liz Skinner, “Sun Will Shine on Solar-Energy Investing, Report Says,” Investment News, June 18, 2007. 11 Cassidy Flanagan, “New Light on Solar Energy,” Business Week, May 17, 2007. SUNPOWER: FOCUSED ON THE FUTURE OF SOLAR POWER Rebecca M. Henderson, Joel Conkling and Scott Roberts Figure 1 PV Module Price and Production History, 1975-2005 PV Module Price History $0.00 $5.00 $10.00 $15.00
  • 67. July 25, 2007 5 SUNPOWER: FOCUSED ON THE FUTURE OF SOLAR POWER Rebecca M. Henderson, Joel Conkling and Scott Roberts Producers and Consumers Japan was the world’s PV shipment leader, shipping more than five times the volume of the United States (Figure 2). Since 2002, Europe had held the number two position after it passed the United States and by 2005, Europe was shipping three times the volume of the United States. Analysts blamed the erosion of U.S. PV market share to a lack of manufacturing incentives and high manufacturing costs. Figure 2 Global PV Shipments, 2000-2005 Global PV Shipments 0 100 200 300 400 500
  • 68. 600 700 800 M W p U.S. Japan Europe ROW U.S. 76.2 96.7 107.8 91.5 140.6 133.6 Japan 96.3 145 233.8 350.6 547 714 Europe 58.5 85.4 123.4 173.1 272.9 406.9 ROW 22 25.8 39.9 60 89.2 153.2 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 Source: Paula Mints, “PV in the U.S.: Where is the market going and how will it get there?”, Renewable Energy Watch, September 2006.
  • 69. Analysts’ expectations that China was the market to watch due to its growing energy needs, large work force and strong industrial base were proven correct in 2006 when China surpassed the United States as the world’s third largest producer of PV cells, behind Germany and Japan. Lacking any kind of domestic incentive/subsidy policy, more than 90% of China’s PV products were exported. Chinese PV producers raised billions of dollars in international IPOs in 2005 and 2006 to build capacity and increase scale with the goal of driving down costs.12 On the consumer side, global PV demand had grown from 114 MWp in 1997 to 505 MWp in 2002 to 1,408MWp in 2005 and 2,500MWp in 2006 and demand was accelerating rapidly particularly in Europe (most especially Germany) and Japan as shown in Figure 3. One prominent analysis of 12 Gail Roberts, “Production Trends and New Technologies Could Push Solar Energy into Mainstream,” Electric Utility Weekly, May 28, 2007. July 25, 2007 6 SUNPOWER: FOCUSED ON THE FUTURE OF SOLAR POWER Rebecca M. Henderson, Joel Conkling and Scott Roberts potential demand at 2006module prices—i.e., around $3.50- $4.50/W with policy support—estimated that there was potential worldwide demand of approximately
  • 70. 5,000MWp, or double 2006 industry sales. Meanwhile, global grid-connected solar capacity was about 5,000MWp. In contrast, installed wind capacity in the United States alone was 9,149MWp.13 Figure 3 Global PV Demand, 2000-2005 Global PV Demand 0 100 200 300 400 500 600 700 800 M W p U.S. Japan
  • 71. Europe ROW U.S. 34.7 43.8 60.8 76 101.8 137.3 Japan 77.9 109.8 176.2 243.8 295.9 392.4 Europe 74.1 120 172.6 232.6 472.4 676.1 ROW 65.3 79.2 95.3 122.9 179.7 202 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 Source: Paula Mints, “PV in the U.S.: Where is the market going and how will it get there?”, Renewable Energy Watch, September 2006. The Solar Value Chain There were five key stages in solar power’s value chain: silicon production, ingot/wafer manufacture, solar cell manufacture, solar module manufacture, and system installation. Firms in the industry differed dramatically in the degree to which they participated in each stage. (Table C shows revenues and profits across the chain.) Table C PV Industry Value Chain Snapshot Year: 2006 Silicon Ingots/Wafers Cells Modules Installatio n # of players 20 40 100 500 5,000 Revenues ($m) 1,400 4,500 7,700 10,200 3,200 Pre-tax margin (%) 53 36 21 5 20
  • 72. Capital costs ($/w/year) 0.65 0.50 0.05 Source: Solar Annual 2006 13 Gail Roberts, “Production Trends and New Technologies Could Push Solar Energy into Mainstream,” Electric Utility Week, May 28, 2007. July 25, 2007 7 SUNPOWER: FOCUSED ON THE FUTURE OF SOLAR POWER Rebecca M. Henderson, Joel Conkling and Scott Roberts July 25, 2007 8 Silicon The key feedstock in the PV industry was high-purity silicon, which was the basis for more than 90% of solar modules. Silicon was obtained from sand through a complex process using numerous purification steps and temperatures up to 1,100ºC which would turn sand into the high purity silicon known as polysilicon.14 As recently as the early 2000s, solar cell producers sourced silicon feedstock mainly from waste silicon discarded during semiconductor manufacturing. This “leftover” silicon supply included high- purity silicon that was slightly above or below the quality specified for semiconductor production, or off-cuts (tops or tails) of monocrystalline ingots. For their part, silicon producers had historically
  • 73. considered solar cell makers a market of last resort, useful for stabilizing fluctuations in the overall semiconductor market but unlikely to amount to meaningful scale. The explosive growth of PV cell manufacturing, however, had transformed the role of solar power in the silicon business. In 2005, the solar industry used approximately 47% of available silicon, and in 2006 it would likely account for the majority share. These fast growing needs had stretched global silicon supply and prices had risen dramatically from $32/kilogram in 2004 under a long-term contract, to $45/kg in 2005, to a predicted $55/kg in 2006 with short-term contracts exceeding $200/kg. However, current investment plans would triple capacity, from 31,000 tons per year in 2005 to 100,000 tons or more by 2010,15 despite the fact that a 5,000 tons/year expansion cost roughly $300 million. The silicon shortage was expected to end around 2008 when supply was estimated to grow 70%.16 Ingots / Wafers Many large solar cell manufacturers had in- house ingot production and wafer sawing capabilities, including REC, SolarWorld, Kyocera, and BP Solar. Dedicated ingot and wafer manufacturers supplied wafers to the solar cell manufacturers that did not have their own ingot and wafer capabilities. Technical progress in the industry had been rapid. In 2004 typical wafers were 250-300 microns thick, and by 2006 they were around 190 microns. However over the same period prices had risen dramatically. In 2004 wafers were sold for around $1.00/watt, while in 2005 the average price was $1.25/watt and in 2006 it was expected to be
  • 74. $1.90/watt. Cells and Modules Solar cell manufacturing was a widely understood process that involved less than ten steps. The largest producers, which included Sharp Solar (Japan), Q-Cells (Germany), Kyocera (Japan), Sanyo (Japan), and Mitsubishi Electric (Japan), together accounted for roughly 58% of the market. Sharp was the clear market leader, with 427.5 MW of production in 2005, nearly three times that of its nearest competitor. Between 50 and 100 manufacturers made up the rest of the industry’s production capacity. 14 Million Roofs handout 15 Policysilicon: Supply, Demand, & Implications for the PV Industry, Prometheus Institute, 2006. 16 Brian Womack, “Alternative Energy Sun Shines on Clean Energy,” Investor’s Business Daily, May 21, 2007. SUNPOWER: FOCUSED ON THE FUTURE OF SOLAR POWER Rebecca M. Henderson, Joel Conkling and Scott Roberts July 25, 2007 9 Due to the global silicon shortage, solar cell prices rose from $2.70/watt in 2004 to $2.50/watt in 2005, and were forecast by Photon Consulting to rise to $3.25/watt in 2006. At expected 2006 prices, pre-tax cell manufacturing profit margins were expected by
  • 75. Photon Consulting to be 21%. While there were roughly 500 smaller module manufacturers in operation in 2006, most of the top cell manufacturers made modules as well. In parallel with increases in PV cell prices, average module prices had also risen from $3.20/watt in 2004 to $3.75/watt in 2005, and were expected to reach $4.30/watt in 2006. System Installation / Integration The most advanced systems integrators had expertise in installing megawatt-scale solar systems at low costs in fields and on large commercial roofs. Competition for these large projects was fierce, and margins were tight even for the best integrators. On the other side of the installation spectrum, small residential installers made up the majority of the 5,000+ solar installers and integrators in operation. In general costs and prices varied widely, depending on the application and geographical region. Total installation costs ranged from $1/watt to $3/watt, and consumer prices ranged from $1.25/watt to $4/watt. For dual-axis trackers in large field installations, area-related costs could reach $1.50-$2.00 per watt, while commercial flat roofs, where aesthetics were less important, were usually around $0.60 per watt. Residential roof installations cost approximately $1.00 per watt for area related costs. While solar installation was fairly simple at a very basic level (one secured racks to the roof and then attached modules to the racks and plugged them in), there could be meaningful first mover advantage for installers that developed expertise in an end-consumer market. For example, the installer that put a system in for a Best Buy could be rewarded with lower costs
  • 76. selling to other ‘big box’ retailers because it understood both the sales process and the needs of that type of customer. Similarly an installer that developed expertise in, for example, residential installations in San Diego, could develop lower costs in residential installation in San Diego than potential entrants. Pricing Deriving an exact price for solar generated electricity was tricky. While conventional power was sold as a flow of power from the grid in units of $/kWhr, solar power was typically sold as an installed system with an upfront capital cost measured in units of $/peak watt. Deriving a flow cost — how much the user would actually pay for kWhrs and how much they would pay per installed watt of generating capacity — depended on a wide range of factors including the life of the system, interest rates, subsidies (if any), hours of sunshine and so on. Hours of sunshine, for example, ranged from nearly six per day in parts of Southern California to 2.5 hours per day in parts of Northern Europe, with important seasonal variation – and both interest rates and the subsidies given to solar power varied widely across the world. SUNPOWER: FOCUSED ON THE FUTURE OF SOLAR POWER Rebecca M. Henderson, Joel Conkling and Scott Roberts
  • 77. In general, however, the average price of solar power ranged from US 25-50¢ per kWh. For example, as Exhibit 2 suggests, the average cost of a residential PV system in California translated into an electricity price, without subsidies, of roughly 31¢/kWh. In contrast, one could generate electricity using conventional power sources for between 4¢/kWh and 6¢/kWh (Exhibit 3). Final prices to the consumer could be significantly higher because electricity was expensive to distribute, but on average conventionally generated electricity was still significantly cheaper than solar power. According to the Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development (OECD), prices for household customers started at just several cents per kWh in areas of Scandinavia and rose to over 25¢/kWh in the highest- priced markets such as Japan. The U.S. average was 9.6¢/kWh in early 2006, with California prices averaging over 13¢/kWh. As Exhibit 4 suggests, however, the average price of electricity told only part of the story. In markets around the world, some customers paid significantly more than the average price of electricity. In California, for example, commercial customers paid 24% more per kWh than residential customers. Meanwhile, the state further stratified prices into five tiers based on total electricity usage per month. As Figure 4 shows, a California customer that consumed more than 34 kWh per day would pay 37¢, Tier 5 prices, for every kWh over the 34 kWh/day limit of Tier 4. Figure 4 California Residential Power Pricing Structure, September 2006
  • 78. - 0.0 5 0.1 0 0.1 5 0.2 0 0.2 5 0.3 0 0.3 5 0.4 0 - 5 1 0 14 19 24 29 34 38 43 48 k W h p e r d a y A ve ra g e H o u se h o ld C o n su m p tio n T ier 1 T ier 2 T ier 3 T ie r 4 T ier 5
  • 79. cen ts p e r kW h Source: Pacific Gas and Electric. Given its high cost, up until the late 1990s, most PV power was used to meet the demands of “off the grid” users. Since that time, however, more solar panels had been sold to residential customers than any other single segment. Panels, attached to the roof of a house or apartment building, could in many cases give households full or near self-sufficiency in power supply. In markets that permitted net metering, households also had the option to sell their excess power to the grid. Under favorable July 25, 2007 10 SUNPOWER: FOCUSED ON THE FUTURE OF SOLAR POWER Rebecca M. Henderson, Joel Conkling and Scott Roberts July 25, 2007 11 pricing (“feed-in tariffs”), this option could dramatically improve the economics of a home PV system. Increasingly, solar systems were also finding a market among large commercial facilities such as big box retail stores, shopping malls, hospitals, and airports. In
  • 80. most cases, solar cells were not substituted completely for grid-based electricity, and customers continued to purchase from the commercial grid. Some commercial customers installed PV systems as a hedge against high electricity prices while others recognized the potential public relations benefits of a “green power” investment. Utility-scale applications were once regarded as the main potential market for solar power. Until the late 1990s, for example, parabolic concentrators at three sites in California’s Mojave Desert accounted for more than 90% of the world’s installed solar capacity.17 However operational and financial challenges had made this vision obsolete. The firm that built the Mojave facilities, Luz International, went out of business. Solar towers were also slow to take off and only a few experimental facilities, mostly under 1 MW, had opened in California, Spain, Israel, Germany, and Australia.18 Policy Support Solar power’s potential to increase energy independence and reduce carbon emissions had led to a wide variety of public subsidies. Around the world, there were more than 1,000 various pro-solar policies put in place by international, national, and local authorities. California’s “Million Solar Roofs” initiative, for example, had allocated $3.2 billion for solar power “buy-downs” through 2016. (A buy-down reduced the upfront capital expenditure required to install a solar system.) In some jurisdictions, customers could sell excess solar power back to their utility at favorable prices. Some governments had set specific targets for the number of
  • 81. households with PV systems, or renewable portfolio standards (RPS) which required utilities to derive a targeted percentage of power from renewable sources and/or solar power. In South Korea, for example, government mandated a target of 1,300 MW of solar power installations by 2012 and in the United States, 24 states had implemented their own RPS. (See Exhibit 5 for list of standards by state.) The U.S. solar market was highly diverse. State regulations and policies toward solar power ranged from the supportive to the non-existent, and power prices, the availability of solar radiation, and public attitudes toward the environment also varied dramatically across states. Exhibit 6 compares the costs and savings for a solar system installed in California, Texas and Massachusetts based on the same monthly electric usage. While a California resident’s estimated net cost would be roughly $17,480, a Massachusetts resident would likely pay nearly twice that amount. Meanwhile, rebates and credits in the state of California ($18,250) equaled half of the installation price. In Texas they were 38% and in Massachusetts 23%. 17 Smil, p.285 18 Ibid. SUNPOWER: FOCUSED ON THE FUTURE OF SOLAR POWER
  • 82. Rebecca M. Henderson, Joel Conkling and Scott Roberts July 25, 2007 12 Quantifying public subsidy policies into a global total of pro- solar spending was difficult, but one analysis estimated that a total of $1.7 billion was spent by governments worldwide in 2005 in supporting solar power, and that this figure would surpass $3 billion in 2006.19 For companies like SunPower subsidy programs were critical in generating demand. But analysts believed that the industry would be able to prop itself up without subsidies by 2012.20 Of course the key to doing so was lowering costs and scaling up production. SunPower SunPower was founded in 1987 by Dr. Richard Swanson, a professor of electrical engineering at Stanford University. At the time it closed its Series A round of VC financing in 1989, SunPower’s goal was to commercialize solar concentrator21 technology. However, according to Swanson, the company ended up going in a different direction: We realized that solar concentrators were a bad idea. Conceivably, someday concentrator systems could be a lower-cost PV alternative, but they are not now and they have a long way to catch up with continually improving flat-plate systems. Moreover, concentrators are not well suited for many small distributed, remote applications. We wrestled with whether we should give the money back to the VCs or not. Ultimately, we chose not to.
  • 83. Starting in about 1991, SunPower went through a long period of trying to find its way. In the early 1990s, the Honda Motor Company approached SunPower asking if the company, known for its efficient solar cells, could make cells big enough to cover Honda’s solar powered race car. After agreeing to Honda’s request, Swanson realized there was one barrier standing in the way of SunPower’s ability to deliver: “We were all from academia. We argued for about four hours one day about whether we needed two shifts or one shift and realized after a while we had no idea how to figure out whether we needed two shifts or one shift.” After hearing about SunPower’s dilemma, …