SlideShare a Scribd company logo
The living commons: A historical understanding
                                                     Anita Cheria and Edwin1
1    Introduction
   A prerequisite to understanding the commons, its use, and governance is an understanding of the power
relations with respect to commons. Power is accentuated by knowledge in action (technology). The restricted
socialisation of knowledge and the control of technology have vastly enhanced the ability to enclose, and
therefore actual enclosure of, the commons.
   The history of commons can be traced as a continuing effort of retaining or reclaiming the commons by the
commoners on the one side, and efforts at enclosure and encroachment by the dominant on the other. The role of
knowledge and technology is critical, since they accentuate the nature of society that underlies it. Knowledge is
organised so that it produces such technology that makes an equitable society more equitable, and an oppressive
one more oppressive. While knowledge systems such as language and ideology provide the inspiration, moral and
intellectual superstructure, technology provides the actual means and tools, empowering humans far beyond their
fragile bodies, almost to the extent of their dreams.
   Understanding the history of enclosures of the physical commons, the fencing of knowledge, and the keen
attempts to re–common them is to take the journey through the centuries, deeply aware of the nature of power and
production relations. It has been a constant seesaw, with the commoners opening up new spaces, reclaiming the
commons while the enclosers, who control the state, find newer ways of enclosure and rent.
   This note looks at the historical developments and the emerging opportunities.
2    What do we mean by commons
   The traditional commons were the spaces of the powerless, of the people who do not have ‘private spaces’
whether for livelihood or leisure. Intimately entwined with their life, these spaces abounded with life, culture, and
tradition. A sacred grove was not empty, but a place where their ancestral spirits still walked, had medicinal plants,
and was inextricably intertwined with their knowledge, their identity, and their very being. Each bit of the ‘empty’
space had a special resonance, each being sentient with the spirits of the trees, plants, and the inanimate.
   The commons can be classified as two, the natural commons and the built commons. The natural commons are
the land, water, air, and their combinations such as the forest, seas, and rivers inclusive of the life in them. It
includes on (land, sea, forests, rivers), above (air, space) and under (minerals, oil, and natural gas) the ground.
With the progress of science, newer commons are being identified such as electromagnetic spectrum and space
itself. Silence is a recognised common now, in 2012, with noise regulation and pollution rules in place, though it
seemed an outlandish idea when Ivan Ilich suggested it in 1982.
   The built commons are two—the hardcoms and the softcoms. The ‘hard’ commons, ‘hardcoms’, are the
physical livelihood systems such as infrastructure built with public resources. Examples of built commons are the
crèches, schools, roads, government buildings such as village offices, post offices, public toilets, and primary
health centres. The hardcoms have a knowledge superstructure. Knowledge spans culture, religion, tradition and
law on the one hand, and information, science, and technology on the other. These are the ‘soft’ part of the built
commons, or the ‘softcoms’. This superstructure is the ‘software’ or the ‘softcoms’ govern the use of hardcoms.
The softcoms determine inclusion, exclusion, access, benefit, and control.
   Commons are managed and shared by a community that is willing and able to defend it. In the mapping and
subsequent fencing of natural resources, the powerful took over the best part and enclosed it for their exclusive
use. The rest shared the commons and were the commoners who formed the community. The powerful (the rich)
have always had their ‘private’ resource base. It is only the powerless (variously called the ‘commons’, the
‘commoners’ or the ‘poor’)2 who were excluded from property, who use spaces ‘in common’ to ensure the
minimum critical mass of space for viability to ensure their own survival. Commons are an attempt to have a
viable resource base by collective usage and stewardship where the laws of property (the ‘formal legal system’)
breakdown. In the modern world too, the phenomenon called ‘secession of the successful’ is seen where the


1 Anita and Edwin are directors of OpenSpace, a human rights and development think tank. The authors thank the Commons
  Initiative, Foundation for Ecological Security, for the many discussions on the commons that helped sharpen concepts and deepen
  understanding. This paper was presented at the National Consultation on Commons, New Delhi, 20-21 April 2012
2 Poverty is a factor of power, not production. For an analysis of the intimate links between poverty and power see M K Bhat, et al
  Life Goes On… 1999, and Anita Cheria et al A Human Rights Approach to Development 2004.
                                                                             The living commons: A historical understanding; page [1]
                                                                                     Anita Cheria and Edwin; office@openspace.org.in
powerful acquire as much territory as possible and fence themselves in ‘gated communities’. We have not evolved
as much as we would like to believe.
    Commons does not always mean open, unrestricted access for all. Visualising ‘the commons’ is often a
romantic imaging of natural resources, most often meadows, rivers, mountains, and forests in their pristine state.
There is a utopian image of them being open access, used without destruction, and always uncontaminated, not
‘despoiled’ by human interference. Human presence, if at all present, is that of the ‘noble savage’. The reality is a
little more complex. These ‘commons’ have been regulated, access restricted and even prohibited, based on
gender, age, faith/belief, caste, or ethnic origin. The ‘commons’ were, and are, rigorously defined in access,
benefits, and control. Significant sections of society are kept out on the basis of caste, gender, or age. The process
of reclaiming the ‘commons’ needs to move beyond utopian imaging to an inclusive framework. At the same time,
the rights to the commons translate into the right to use, the right of security to tenure, and the right to stewardship
—very different from the concept of ‘ownership’ of ‘property’ that the law understands, and tries to foist upon
communities in the name of joint and community title deeds (patta, khata).
    Increasingly the terminology of ‘commons’ is used by the dominant to claim the right to what are essentially
the ‘commons of the poor’ for resource extraction and waste disposal. This forcible commoning is nothing but
resource capture after the dominant have destroyed their ‘property’. It is no coincidence that biodiversity is richest
in ‘underdeveloped’ areas, and that ‘developed’ areas are monoculture deserts. It is no coincidence either, that the
indigenous people resist this invasion of their commons, or that there are literally thousands of struggles when the
state tries to invade and occupy the commons of the poor by terming them ‘national’ commons. The west,
unsurprisingly, calls these as ‘global’ commons and plans to use them as carbon sinks and other forms of waste
absorbers or the indigenous knowledge—very much a part of knowledge and creative commons—as ‘raw
material’ for their intellectual ‘property’.
    The health of the commons is intrinsically linked to the health of the community and the health of every
commoner in such a tight correlation that one cannot exist without the other. Commons play a strategic role in
maintaining ecological health, reducing poverty, and improving collective action. Those who want to destroy a
community destroy their commons and those who want to destroy the commons destroy their community. One is a
prerequisite for the other. As long as a community willing and able to defend its commons exists, that commons
will survive.
3    The importance of vocabulary
3.1 Commons and vocabulary
   There is a world of difference between the commons and common property. Though abbreviated as CPR,
common pool resources are very different from common property regimes. The blurring of this distinction,
sometimes inadvertent but oftentimes deliberate, has led to many avoidable conflicts, the displacement and
alienation of the commoner from the commons, and the loss of the commons itself.
   ‘Commons’ is outside the property framework, while ‘public property’ is within the property framework—
islands within private property. In legal terms, commons would be res communes, property that is public due to its
very nature, while public property would be res publicae belonging and open to the public by virtue of law. In
parts of India (Rajasthan, Punjab and Haryana), Samlat/Samlati from ‘shamlat’ is still used widely in village
common law. The term had its origins in the Mughal era Urdu/Farsi term ‘shamil’ meaning to include (in Arabic
‘comprehensive’, ‘inclusive’, ‘universal’ and even ‘perfect’). ‘Shamilat’ approximates to ‘inclusive’ or ‘shared’,
both of which are core values of the commons. The ‘Sambhar Shamlat’ is a revenue arrangement for the salt lake
of Sambhar instituted jointly by the kingdoms of Jaipur and Jodhpur in pre–British India. In Tamilnadu, the term
Poramboke is used.
   There is an intimate linkage between the language used to describe the commons and the perception and use of
commons—how ‘the commons’ have been translated from practice to restrictive usage. The reduction of thought
to ideas, ideas to concepts to language and then to words, speech, and writing results in transmission loss at every
stage. Though languages by themselves are not deterministic, they do have a certain bias in that direction. The
words used to describe become words used to determine. This determinism becomes even more pronounced when
translated into the written form of the language and then to law. When translated into law which determines
action, it results in linguistic deficiencies restricting action—a serious lacuna which impedes progress on
protection, use and benefits of the commons. What is written becomes the legal limit. Just as language has been
used to bind, it can just as usefully be employed to liberate the commons and return it to the commoners and the

                                                                   The living commons: A historical understanding; page [2]
                                                                           Anita Cheria and Edwin; office@openspace.org.in
community. The vocabulary of the law is the vocabulary of property. The conflict between the law and those who
break it is often the conflict between the deterministic nature of the written word and the descriptive intent.
3.2 Socio–linguistics: The vocabulary of property and industrial society
   Words reveal the nature of society, social relations, and even offer clues to their physical environment. For
instance, languages of tropical lands have few words for snow, while the Eskimo have more than a dozen. If the
language of a society embeds space with life, with animals, plants, and the inanimate, then ‘development’ in the
language of that society would not cut through the migration paths of animals or fence their waterholes.
Unfortunately, the dominant paradigm privileges industry and capital. The industrial revolution gave rise to
capitalism and democracy. The jurisprudence that developed at the time gave rise to its own vocabulary with
industrial relations as the normative. The vocabulary of individual private property and individual rights
developed co–terminus with science, industrialisation, capitalism and democracy. In a rather frank statement of its
objectives, industry tells us that ‘development’ is to ‘exploit’ natural resources. Efficiency is to do it in the fastest
time possible. Anything that does not directly affect their bottom line, or what they can get away with—for
instance dumping pollution into the air and water—was not counted as a ‘cost’ but as an ‘externality’ by which
they could maximise book profits. The language of commons is to protect natural resources. Efficiency is to
minimise the resource use footprint. Greenfield is very different from green field—spaces make a lot of difference
in language too!
   The present vocabulary developed as a vocabulary of private property since commons was the norm and
implicit. Property was a subset of the commons. The king owned all else. (It is from the ‘royal’ or ‘regal’ estates
that we have the term ‘real’ estate.) At the time ‘wastes’ meant any uninhabited land, and what are private fields
today were called ‘closes’. There needed to be terms to distinguish property from the commons, since property
was a subset of the commons. Unfortunately, the language of property has become so dominant that there is a role
reversal, and in extreme cases there is even denial of commons due to absence of explicit definition or description.
   Wastes were places where there were no people. This land did not produce tax. Though there is a lot of
difference between wastes and waste, there was an erroneous association between ‘wasteland’ and ‘waste’. For the
king, wastes were land that was wasted or useless, since it was not a source of revenue. Though it was not land
that was wasted for the people, who did a lot of hunting there and used it for a variety of purposes, in the
dominant discourse (which includes the law), the perspective of the commoner has seldom found space or
resonance. This wasteland is then alienated to the private industry—i.e. made into property—so that it can be
taxed and made ‘productive’. However, production for the manor is very different from production for the
community.
   The dominant usage in modern languages is steeped in property. It is property—whether industrial or capital—
that is taken as the normative. In law, defence of property is normative. The word ‘development’ in modern usage
implicitly refers to industrial development. In more traditional languages, development always means human
development—of the individual and the community. In English however, human development must be specified.
Similar usage is seen in terms such as ‘growth’, ‘profit’, ‘structural adjustment’ and ‘reforms’. While The
Reformation was to de–institutionalise the church and knowledge, the present day ‘reforms’ are to make polity
and society itself more market centric. Therefore these would more accurately be termed deform and deformation
from a social and human centric perspective.
   The consequence of the industrial framework is that industrial intervention is a prerequisite for a life pattern to
be recognised, value to be assigned and to disregard the active commons. Language is so influenced by the
industrial paradigm that nature is considered empty until mechanical procedures are applied to it. Value comes
only from such addition, and soon value is mistaken for price. Since the tools are to measure industrial production,
all else is termed empty. However, the tools developed by industrial society measured only the health of the
enclosures, the corporations, to the detriment of the larger good. Growth was seen to be good, divorced from its
effects on society at large, to the verge of being growth for growth sake. Terms such as ‘jobless growth’ were
invented and used, not even recognising the irony, that the purposeless growth described therein closest resembles
cancer in the real world.
   Where there is no industrial intervention, it was considered terra nullius. Earlier, ‘wastes’, though an
anthropocentric definition, were not considered empty and certainly not a vacuum. The ‘informal economy’,
though the largest in ‘less developed economies’, has no place in the GDP just because it is not measured. Air is
considered empty and lifeless, so smoke and other pollutants can be let into it, no matter the bees and pollination

                                                                    The living commons: A historical understanding; page [3]
                                                                            Anita Cheria and Edwin; office@openspace.org.in
are vital for forests and agriculture, apart from the insignificant detail of humans needing fresh air to breathe. The
indiscriminate use of air and electromagnetic resources have literally pushed out bees and birds, in some cases
leading to large scale deaths. The rivers and seas are considered empty so the sewage and toxic waste is poured
into them. It extended even to considering ‘the natives’ minds as empty and bereft of culture—terra nullius of the
mindscape—if there was no industrial production. As Eric Fromm put it in ‘To Be or To Have,’ Industrial society
has contempt for nature—as well as for all things that are not machine made and for all people who are not
machine makers. What is not, or cannot, be measured is considered absent.
3.3 Vocabulary of transition: Commons to property
   The change of usage from commons to common property signals a significant shift in production relations, and
the actual relationship between the community and the commons. The commons has always been outside the
property framework. When ‘commons’ becomes ‘common property’ it brings the commons firmly within the
property framework, enabling the government to enforce the concept of ‘terra nullius’ and ‘eminent domain’. Law,
the language of the state, is in the vocabulary of property. The introduction of property introduces ‘trespasser’ and
the related term ‘criminal’. Where there is no property, there cannot be trespass. The slip is then rapid: from
commons to common property to public property, government property, public private partnership (PPP), and
finally private property. PPP itself has different levels: Build Own Transfer (BOT), Build Own Operate Transfer
(BOOT) and joint ventures (JV).
   The state would like to blur the distinction between them and use these terms interchangeably. Their distinct
histories, and therefore the legal distinction, must always be kept in mind, because the key difference is in their
treatment of ‘property’. This alertness is required due to the central role played by the state in alienating the
commons from the commoner. The state would see this creeping acquisition as a right of the state. In a curious
reversal, the encroacher state claims that the commoners are encroachers in the commons, and seeks to ‘clear the
encroachments’ by evicting the commoners. The commoners, who are indigenous to the commons, cannot be
encroachers on the commons. In a curious reversal, encroaching governments around the world routinely label the
commoners as encroachers—akin to calling Indians illegal aliens in India—and evicts them from the commons.
3.4 Vocabulary in the urban commons
   In the urban or ‘built commons’ this gradual transformation is seen in the slow transition from being human
centric to machine centric in the progression: path—street—road—highway—expressway. In a path humans are
supreme. There is no mechanised transport. Human powered transport such as cycles and carts are rare. In a street
too, humans are supreme. Mechanised transport is rare and of the smaller variety. In roads, the primary users—the
human beings—are relegated to the sidewalks, and are decidedly second class. This marginalisation turns to
exclusion in highways and expressways, where ‘slow moving transport’ is excluded and actively discouraged.
They are often fenced off. Community spaces—for hawkers or pleasantries—are possible only on streets,
pavements, and footpaths.
   The notion of roads being for the public—a ‘commons’—has taken a beating in recent years. Footpaths are an
essential part of roads, since that is the part of the road that is used by the vendors, pedestrians and those who use
public transport. This space is being severely restricted, and sometimes even absent, in cities—both in city centres
and in residential neighbourhoods. Instead the roads are being broadened to make space for private vehicles.
Though most people travel by public transport, very little space is earmarked for bus lanes, bus stops/bus bays,
and passenger shelters at bus stops or footpaths. Cycle tracks are not only absent, use of ‘slow moving’
transportation is prohibited on most flyovers and arterial roads. Footpaths shrink and disappear. This invasion of
the street and conquest of the footpath is to have wider roads so that high–rises can be built with larger Floor
Space Index (FSI). The vendors have to be removed so that the malls can survive. Non–rivalrous commons
suddenly become rivalrous.
   Language has undergone significant change from the urban commons (‘public’) to urban enclosure: from
gardens to parks (off limits to animals including pets), with manicured lawns (off limits to humans too), from
markets to malls, from streets to flyovers, and playgrounds to stadiums. Increased crime and aggression, as rest
and recreation spaces were commandeered for private use, is a result of this enclosure. New usage such as ‘gated
communities’ invading the vocabulary mark the success of enclosure movements and the disconnect of the elite
from economic production, cultural vibrancy, and democracy of the city.



                                                                  The living commons: A historical understanding; page [4]
                                                                          Anita Cheria and Edwin; office@openspace.org.in
3.5 The exclusive sacred: Constructing knowledge and the architecture of language
   The definition of commons and its legal defence rests on the knowledge base. The knowledge base rests on the
language employed. The construction of knowledge and the architecture of language is therefore fundamental to
the defence of the commons. The physical commons needs the support of knowledge commons such as culture,
religion, tradition, law, science, and technology. A fundamental and critical challenge of the knowledge commons
is that only some knowledge is acknowledged as knowledge itself, the modern day version of ‘my superstition is
scripture but your scriptures are myths’.
   This enables those of the ‘true knowledge’ to define what is the commons and what is private, who owns what
and what is legitimate. The keepers of ‘true knowledge’ can then determine access, control, privilege, and
exclusion from the commons. Religion and culture are ways of organising knowledge. They are for enclosing the
commons and used as such by the powerful. Though claiming to be ‘universal’—and therefore the ‘commons’ of
at least humanity—major religions of the world still are exclusivist not only towards others (calling them pagan,
infidel, kafir, Asura, Daeva) but also to those within its fold. The duality enables forced inclusion for resource
grab and exclusion for benefits.
   Though knowledge was shared within the community, the ‘community’ was narrowly defined. It often meant
only the male of a sub–sect of a sub–clan. Priesthood is a virtual male monopoly, with different levels of initiation
over long periods of trial being a prerequisite for greater access. Knowledge was privatised and jealously guarded
by making them ‘sacred’ and only for the ‘chosen’. In extreme cases, even the knowledge of the ‘sacred language’
was prohibited. The poor were not even allowed to learn the language of power—whether Sanskrit, Latin or
English. ‘Scriptures’ were kept hidden from the commons, who could not know what they said.
   Ideological systems such as religion, caste (Varna), race, and patriarchy worked in tandem to reinforce each
other and regulate the use of the resources, slowly but inexorably with grinding finality, fencing off the commons.
Most often, this ‘regulation’ is to restrict or even prohibit certain sections from using the commons. Slowly, the
majority was kept away from ‘the commons’ for various reasons. With ‘might as right’ being the norm, only what
could not be enclosed by the dominant remained commons—and the ‘could not’ diminished with every advance of
science and technology.
3.6 From property to commons
   Despite all the talk of ‘commons’ the government sees and can comprehend only ‘grazing land’ or ‘pasture’,
and the commoners as ‘encroachers’. The market and the corporate world see the commons as property–in–the–
waiting, to be taken over when they have the capacity.
   Retaking the commons needs a vocabulary of commons—in thought (attitude), speech, policy (intent), law
(norms) and programmes (practice). The vocabulary of the commons cannot be a vocabulary of property. To
define the commons as common property is to fall into the trap of property relations. Just as a gender just society
needs gender inclusive and gender just vocabulary (human, spokesman, spokesperson, spokeswoman), defending
the commons needs a vocabulary of commons.
4    Enclosure and re–commoning
4.1 Commons and the state
   There are many views on the emergence and growth of state. One is that as the family grew the father (or
dominant male) became the head of the clan, tribe and finally the king. The other is that the king was the chief of a
group of marauders who was paid protection money by the sedentary population to be left alone.
   The ‘king as father’ kingdoms gave rise to the welfare state, while the ‘king as robber’ gave rise to the colonial,
rent–seeking state. This has coloured most discussions on the role of the state, since those coming from different
kinds of states would want a larger or smaller role for the state depending on their experience. In India, the state as
we know it now, arose from the colonial state, and therefore is extractive.
   However, history has proved that the state, no matter what its origin, has always turned against its people in the
long run, and is a protector of class interests. Though the state can, and does, temporarily align with the interests
of the citizens and mouth pro–citizen slogans even longer, the true long–term nature of the state is against
communities and commons.
4.2 The feudal era
   Some collective functions were done by the king for the welfare of the entire kingdom. Good kings used the
tax, or protection money, for common services. Depending on your view, these common services were provided
by the state because the king was the father and had to take care of his children or because the infrastructure
                                                                  The living commons: A historical understanding; page [5]
                                                                          Anita Cheria and Edwin; office@openspace.org.in
would provide more efficient means of extraction from the subjects. Kings built tanks for water storage and roads
—the first built commons. As kings expanded their territory, they were assimilative of other cultures. In religion,
all gods were fitted into a pantheon, with their relative positions reflecting the strength of their followers on earth.
Slowly these were assimilated into a trinity, and then into one all powerful god—the god of the king—who not
only owned everything in the universe but was the creator of the universe. The Earth and everything in it belonged
to this god. Theoretically, the god was the ‘god of all’, though in practice access to the ‘god of all’ was highly
restricted, reflecting the restrictions on the use of ‘commons’. The ‘god of all’ translated into the concept of
‘eminent domain’ which means that the king, or the state, owned everything. The people only had the right to use.
The king could extinguish all ‘rights’ at will, including the life of the subjects. The father had similar rights in the
family.
   The idea that the Earth ‘belonged’ to someone—and that we are not ‘of the earth’—was necessary to subjugate
the Earth and other beings, including humans. Ownership is always of the ‘lesser’ (woman in patriarchal societies,
nature in non–indigenous communities) not of an equal or sacred. First, a god who was outside of creation was
created and made ‘the creator’. Then came the identification of the king with the god—either as a direct avatar, or
as a descendant. Intellectuals, bards, priests, and other sycophants developed theories of the ‘divine right of kings’
and the ‘scriptures’ that had laws legitimising ownership of the ‘nobility’ and exclusion of the ‘commoners’ (being
two sides of a coin). Unfortunately, kings began to believe in the sycophantic paeans, like many who believe their
own propaganda and advertisements today.
   ‘Kings’ whose dominion barely covered a few acres declared themselves lords of the universe, the seven
heavens, and the three worlds. The king being a god could, and did, exploit the commons—the people and the
resources—since he was ‘outside’ and ‘above’, and therefore ‘greater’, than nature. The commoners were not
‘greater’ than nature, and therefore could not ‘exploit’. This ‘externalising’ is the key distinction between
indigenous peoples and all others. For the indigenous people, nature—life—community is a continuum. For all
others there is an external god who created and controls nature. Externalising would return as the more pernicious
‘externalities’ of the industrial economy and tools of measurement, which enabled distorted and fundamentally
flawed tools to pass off dubious ‘cost benefit analysis’ as science.
   Exploitation of nature had to await the industrial revolution. The Cartesian formulation created an ideological
framework that made it possible for humans to consider themselves as separate from, and superior to, nature. The
Cartesian framework resulted in tremendous increase in knowledge, science, and technology, but also made it
possible for Homo sapiens to dominate nature on a global scale. Technology made it possible to reach across the
spatial ‘buffers’ between communities to dominate and enclose.
4.3 The need for enclosures
   Enclosures are not always bad and are sometimes even required, such as for security, risk and innovation. The
first ‘fencing’ was probably to keep off marauders, the remnants of the hunter gatherers who preyed on the
sedentary agriculturists. Enclosure became more common and permanent as the pressure on the land grew and the
‘buffer land’ between communities and individuals diminished, changing non-rivalrous commons into rivalrous
commons. Though there was always a territorial component in human habitation, and territories were marked,
they followed natural boundaries of hills and streams. There were markers, first bio-markers such as trees and
later dressed stones, delimiting territories. Delimiting land was seldom for exclusive use, and non-rivalrous usage
was permitted. But markers are very different from privatising land though fencing. Fencing brought in the
concept of exclusive use. As the capacity to fence grew, so did the extent of land fenced and the duration. Record
keeping and technology enhance fencing infinitely.
   In agrarian societies, small patches of land could be marked for use by individuals and families but these
reverted to the community or the state. These closes were places where there could be risk/innovation within the
carrying capacity of the community. Once the innovation was successful, the fruits were shared by the community.
There was sufficient space so that the risks were isolated, and the footprint of the communities did not overlap.
   The capacity of a community to risk is dependent on how secure it is—meaning the state of its buffers, surplus,
and how far it is from the survival levels. At survival levels, no community can afford to break away from the
tried and tested, i.e. take risk or innovate. Innovation even if it be individual initiative, can only be within the
capacity of community to bear the cost of failure without harming security of the community as a whole.
Enclosures provide this opportunity and security—as in today’s science laboratories where experiments are
conducted in a controlled, isolated space. Only the benefits are released onto the commons. Similar was the case

                                                                   The living commons: A historical understanding; page [6]
                                                                           Anita Cheria and Edwin; office@openspace.org.in
with the capitalist invention of the corporation, which was to ring fence the risk so that it did not affect the entire
wealth of the investor.
4.4 Commoning knowledge
    The earliest known attempt to common knowledge in India was by the Buddha (563–486BC), who taught in
Pali, the language of the commons. It is no coincidence that both of India’s ancient universities—at Nalanda and
Taxila—were Buddhist with about 10,000 students and a teacher student ratio of 1:5. For his trouble, the
gatekeepers of knowledge exterminated Buddhism from the land of its origin. A similar attempt to common
knowledge had to await the advent of Mohammed in Arabia in the seventh century—over a thousand years—who
ensured that Islam was taught in the language of the commons, Arabic. Ironically, it was the adherents of Islam
who sacked both the Buddhist universities.
    Though Christianity was taught in Aramaic, the language of the people, its texts were in Hebrew, Greek and
Latin—all languages of the gatekeepers. It reached such a level of exclusion that Europe, where the Roman
Catholic church held sway, fell into the ‘age of faith’ or the ‘dark ages’—a term coined by a Roman Catholic
Priest. ‘Dark’ in this context meant absence of written records. Literacy levels were close to zero. It took the
Reformation, and the insistence of the Protestant Christians on schooling and literacy, for the Roman Catholics to
turn their attention to literacy in the Counter Reformation.
    In the millennial belief system on the return of Christ, Christendom launched an attack to ‘liberate the holy
land’ at the time of his second coming. The contact of the Europeans with the Arabs during the crusades (1095–
1291) led to the Renaissance (14 th century) and the Reformation (14 th to 16th centuries)—helped in no small
measure by the printing press (1440)—that helped democratisation of knowledge. One of the first books to be
printed was the Bible, first in Latin and then in the local languages of the people, again making ‘knowledge’
accessible to the commons (the translators were burnt at the stake). With typical German efficiency, the hitherto
restricted–to–the–Roman–Catholic–clergy system of education was thrown open to anyone with an interest in
studying. An illiterate child could be taught cutting edge knowledge with industrial precision within five years. A
decade of schooling was all it took to churn out ‘bachelors’ and ‘masters’ in various specialities—something that
took a lifetime before.
    The schooling system—which socialises knowledge and social mores—was refined over the years so that an
illiterate five year old going into the system would understand Nobel Prize winning concepts in less than ten
years. However, the dominant soon struck back, and coopted the ‘new normal’. Even today, with ‘universal
education’ the rich (privileged) are taught to command and consume and the middle class to manage and save. The
poor, as always, are taught to obey and sacrifice. In a commons framework, we would have a commons school
system that encourages cooperation. The absence of such a system shows up in very many different ways. The
multi–tier schooling system teaches all children for 15 years that collaboration is bad and greed is good—and then
society wonders why adults are so selfish and so corrupt.
    The unintended consequence of the printing press and increased literacy was that oral traditions were wiped
out, de–legitimised, or made ‘less’ in short order especially within the legal system. Only written titles and
contracts were recognised. Much of the commons were enclosed as reserve forest and exclusive enclaves with the
stroke of a pen. Five centuries on, oral traditions have not recovered from this knockout blow, despite
development in audio visual technology. With this explosion of knowledge and scientific enquiry came the Age of
Reason and the industrial revolution, which enabled fencing on a global scale.
4.5 Colonialism, corporations, capitalism
   The imperial overreach of the crusades had a debilitating effect on most European monarchies. The crusade–
weakened kings were almost bankrupt. They could not conquer the land required to expand their tax base to
support their lifestyle. They could not raise taxes on their war weary subjects. Instead, the subjects wrested
concessions from them. The Magna Carta, possibly the first citizens’ charter limiting the duties of the king, was
signed in 1215. The commoners realised governance—and the capacity to defend the commons—was intrinsic to
the commons and they needed to be present when laws and decisions were made regarding the commons. So the
House of Commons was established in the 13th and 14th centuries.
   The surplus (extraordinary profits) created by the industrial revolution made capital accumulation possible, and
the merchant class wealthy enough to build ships and launch to foreign lands—something that only kings could do
before. So the kings let some of their citizens go out and conquer other (non–Christian) lands for a part of the
profits. These citizens would have the exclusive right to plunder the foreign land and its people for a short period
                                                                  The living commons: A historical understanding; page [7]
                                                                          Anita Cheria and Edwin; office@openspace.org.in
(similar to patent and copyright) since the conquest was still in the framework of eminent domain. A ‘Royal
Charter’ was granted to the Dutch East India Company (DEIC, 1602–1800), British East India Company (BEIC,
1600–1858), and Massachusetts Bay Company (MBC, 1629–1684). DEIC was granted monopoly for 21 years
only. The MBC Charter was ‘forever’ subject to payment of 20% tax but was revoked in 55 years. The 15 year
monopoly of BEIC was made indefinite in 1609, but the monopoly was revoked by the East India Company Act
1813 (the Charter Act). BEIC had only about a fifth of the business of DEIC, and yet controlled a substantial part
of India. Revocation of the charter of BEIC and MBC brought these lands under the direct rule of the British
Crown.
   The corporation as a legal entity was formed, so that the investors could share profits or loss according to the
investment. Initially, these companies were incorporated for a single voyage and disbanded with the sharing of its
profits. With increase in surplus, the corporations became more permanent with multiple ships and multiple
voyages at any given time. Private armies and navies were raised for the protection of the armadas and trade
routes. The corporation limited (fenced) the risk to the money invested, and did not extend liability to the entire
assets of the investor. The monarch got a share in the profit, and was not liable for any loss. This corporation was
a fairly ‘democratic’ entity. With the development of capitalism came democracy, where one man would have one
vote (equal share in governance of a nation) just as in a company it was a share in profit in proportion to
investment. It was, in a sense, ‘commoning governance’ in the new lands, just as the commoners fought for, and
got, the House of Commons in the British Parliament.
   In the foreign lands considered ‘empty’, terra nullius, the colonisers literally and figuratively fenced off land for
their own use. Technology made it possible to fence ever larger areas at increasing distances. Large parts of Africa
and Asia were enclosed as game reserves and restrictions were placed on indigenous use of land. Most of this was
accomplished through iniquitous declarations and treaties, enforced by the iron fist. To prevent internecine
conflict, areas of influence were agreed upon by European powers drawing straight lines on a map. These
artificially separated communities and did not have natural geography as borders, leading to many present
conflicts, along with the development of technology.
4.6 Democratising knowledge and governance
   In the colonies, among themselves, the colonisers could move beyond the social and economic boundaries
imposed on them by their own societies and nations with some limited social mobility. They freed themselves
from the tyranny of the kings and established the rule of law.
   The commons were beneficiaries of many of the innovations of the companies, chiefly the transparent rule of
law (especially contracts), and set procedures of governance. The State could no longer just seize everything.
There had to be a clear procedure. Retrospective changes were not permitted. The law of contracts was used by
John Locke (1632–1704) when he argued that the king also had a contract with his subjects, and if he broke the
contract he could be deposed. The spread of knowledge meant that everyone could have a copy of the contract,
and understand what it was explicitly. The modern written constitutions—the contract between the State and the
commons—are a direct result. In keeping with the secularisation of knowledge, these contracts have a scope for
amendments, a distinction that sets apart these secular ‘bibles’ of the state from the holy books of faith based
ideologies which are supposed to be ‘revealed’ and ‘unchangeable’ though incompatible and irrelevant to
contemporary times. They are a commoning of governance, keeping pace with contemporary times. Unfortunately
for the colonised, might was right. When the king or the corporation could, they did seize the land and violate the
law.
   In India, the schooling system established by Christian missionaries who piggybacked on the mercantile
conquest brought knowledge back to the commoners to a degree not witnessed since Buddhist days. Though the
first printed Indian work was released on 6 November 1556, the revolution started with 1793 when the trickle
turned into a flood that would churn out 86 dictionaries, 115 grammar books and 45 journals in 73 languages of
India (apart from the Bible in each of these languages) in a short span. With the backing of the state and the
printing press, they could make available books, and therefore knowledge, at an affordable price to the commoner
on a scale hitherto unimaginable. Secularising knowledge by setting up the schooling system—first set up to
produce clerks for the colonial administration—provided for a lot of upward mobility. Both Ambedkar and
Mahatma Phule acknowledged that the advent of the British was far from an unmitigated disaster for the
depressed classes. On the contrary, it was a qualified blessing.


                                                                   The living commons: A historical understanding; page [8]
                                                                           Anita Cheria and Edwin; office@openspace.org.in
4.7 The dance of the dinosaurs
   A couple of centuries after the charters, the companies themselves fell victim to hubris and imperial overreach,
and the natives were in revolt everywhere. These companies had fine–tuned their exploitative mechanisms and it
was no longer a light touch revenue extraction. Just as the kings before them, these companies exhausted
themselves in conquests and turned to the kings for protection or support. The monarchs who were content with
taxes, and had rebuilt their strength in the interregnum, could not allow the lucrative revenue stream to dry up, and
so directly stepped in with their armed forces to secure the estates and trading posts of the companies. The
colonies were brought directly under the British Crown (Massachusetts in 1686, India in 1858), making for global
enclosures as against the enclosures within national boundaries earlier. Internally, the rejuvenated state in the 18 th
century reverted to its old policy of maximising revenue extraction by taxing even the sunlight streaming into
houses, by linking taxes to the number of windows. Though they opened up the knowledge commons, the colonial
system fenced ever larger parts of the countryside.
   As with most second comings, the second coming of the state met with disaster, after initial ‘success’. Within a
hundred years most of the known world was colonised, the rapid explosion of technology making even more
fencing possible. The turn of the 20th century saw a race for colonisation and resources on an unprecedented scale.
This race to fence off the world saw a deepening exclusion of the colonised people from their own lands in greater
degree. It could not but end in conflict which, in 1945, resulted in the creation of a new world order after two
debilitating wars by the imperial powers in 20 years.
   With the imperial powers weakened by the global wars, the locals again asserted themselves and reclaimed the
commons. This led to a host of wars of national liberation, and many new nations were formed in the 1940s–
1960s. Unfortunately, the locals took over the colonial state and the fences remained. Though there were attempts
at recommoning such as nationalising common resources, the state structure remained the same. The world was
fenced off between the Capitalist and Soviet blocs. There were sub–blocs within this, as the US continued with the
Monroe Doctrine of hemispheric dominance, or in blunt terms, considering the whole of the Americas as its
‘backyard’ where it alone could have any military role, while projecting its military power in remote corners of the
globe. The new nation states enforced various copycat forms of restriction, from actual fencing to increasingly
intrusive and restrictive visa regimes.
   Social movements were at the forefront of the recommoning effort. The Suffragettes in the late 19th century, and
the feminist movement since the 1960s, tried to being women into the global commons in governance and all
public spaces. The most significant successes were that of the women’s movement, closely followed by the civil
rights movements (anti-race in USA, and anti-caste in India). These movements directly challenged the fencing of
the commons by patriarchy and race/caste. Women, blacks and Dalits demanded and got the right to vote, study,
and enter ‘public’ spaces. The anti-war/peace movements demanded that common resources not be wasted for
defending the hegemony of the elites or for their turf wars but be used for common good.
   Capitalism (which started off by breaking the fences put up by feudalism but had by now become another name
for privatisation and fencing) struck back using the International Monetary Fund (IMF) and the World Bank. The
newly created states were targeted by, in John Perkins famous phrase, ‘economic hit–men’. Structural adjustment,
essentially privatising national resources and buying up the local leaders, was the norm to ensure that iniquitous
regimes continued. The Regan—Thatcher revolution in both sides of the Atlantic pummelled the commons and
the commoners in the 1980s. Public utilities—including water—were privatised in the UK. There was talk of
shrinking the state so that it could be flushed down the toilet. With the collapse of the Soviet Union in 1990,
capitalist triumphalism even proclaimed the ‘end of history’.
   The 1990s saw an even more savage round of privatisation that fenced not only the existing resources but laid
claim to any that could possibly be discovered anywhere in the universe. GATT (General Agreement in Trade and
Tariffs) was followed by the World Trade Organisation (WTO) with its GATS (General Agreement on Trade and
Services), IPR (Intellectual Property Rights), TRIPS (Trade Related Intellectual Property Rights), TRIMS (Trade
Related Investment Measures), and GAA (General Agreement on Agriculture). New acronyms GM (Genetically
Modified) and BT (Biotechnology) found their way into everyday lexicon. Everything became ‘property’ and
whatever possible was even physically enclosed.
   Agreements under the WTO ensure that the knowledge of the industrial societies is kept private while opening
up the traditional knowledge as global commons. The World Economic Forum (WEF), a private club with
membership of the world’s thousand leading companies, which started in 1971 increased in power and prestige in
the 1990s. Its annual meetings in Davos decided the global economic policy for the year. This private club had
                                                                  The living commons: A historical understanding; page [9]
                                                                          Anita Cheria and Edwin; office@openspace.org.in
governments come in only as invitees—a reversal of roles that accurately reflected the changed power relations
and the state of the commons.
   Copyright, initially for 14 years, extended progressively to the life of the author and beyond. It became life of
author plus 40, to 50, to 60 years, and now is life of the author plus 100 years. Biotechnology led to the unveiling
of the human genome, and consequently the patenting of life. The growing privatisation of knowledge resulted in
work on GM crops. These crops were considered so commercially valuable that they had a killer gene inserted
into them so that they would not be able to reproduce—the farmer would have to get back to the company for the
next year’s seeds. Despite polluting adjacent farms, the scientists and marketers thought of their invention as
valuable—so much so that they referred to the bees (responsible for most pollination) as ‘pollen robbers’. The
mind had become completely warped. The government was captured by the mercantile barons and cared more
about consumers than citizens. Even essentials such as water became a commodity and many believed in market
pricing water. ‘User fees’ were proposed. Public utility services were handed over to corporations. Rivers were
privatised. Bottled water made its appearance. The tipping point was probably 2003 when, for the first time in
history, a majority (52 of 100) of the world’s largest economies were corporations and not nation–states.
5    The commons today
5.1 Recognising the fundamental right to commons
   Within a decade of Capitalism’s triumphalism, the Labour Party (PT) came to power in southern Brazil—in the
triumphalist American ‘backyard’. To celebrate they started the ‘World Social Forum’ which grew to be a world
assembly of the commons. The organising principles of the WSF are radically different from other such
assemblies—no joint statement, no spokespersons, and multiple locations spanning the globe.
   Since then, the South and Central American peoples have been at the forefront of the global transition to
commons. The pushback ‘recommoning’ was most dramatic in the case of water in the first decade of the 21 st
century. By the middle of the decade, water was recommoned in Bolivia. In 2006, the water utility company Suez
was removed from La Paz Bolivia. It was forced out of Buenos Aires and Santa Fe, Argentina soon after.
Adelaide, Australia took back its water from a private consortium after years of being engulfed in a ‘big pong’
(stench) caused by leaking sewers. In India the secretive plans of the World Bank to force privatisation in New
Delhi were stalled in 2005.
   Water as a right was recognised legally by Uruguay on 31 October 2004. South Africa, Ecuador, Ethiopia and
Kenya declared water as a human right in their constitutions. In April 2005 the Belgian Parliament passed a
constitutional amendment recognising water as a human right. In August 2006, the Indian Supreme Court ruled
that protection of natural lakes and ponds is akin to honouring the right to life—the most fundamental right of all.
In September 2006 the French Senate accepted ‘the right to access to clean water’. The Netherlands declared the
‘right to water’ through a constitutional amendment in 2008.
   In January 2011 the Supreme Court of India ordered the protection of the commons, eviction of encroachers
and periodic compliance reports in the case before it on encroachment of the village pond, but which it suo moto
enlarged to cover all commons. Interestingly, it made a distinction between the encroachers and the commoners
directing that the commoners should not be evicted.
    Before parting with this case we give directions to all the State Governments in the country that they should
    prepare schemes for eviction of illegal/unauthorized occupants of Gram Sabha/ Gram Panchayat/
    Poramboke/ Shamlat land and these must be restored to the Gram Sabha/ Gram Panchayat for the common
    use of villagers of the village. [...] Regularization should only be permitted in exceptional cases e.g. where
    lease has been granted under some Government notification to landless labourers or members of
    Scheduled Castes/Scheduled Tribes, or where there is already a school, dispensary or other public utility
    on the land.
                                                Para 22, CIVIL APPEAL NO.1132 /2011 @ SLP(C) No.3109/2011
   Britain too started the process of restoration of commons with the deeply flawed Commons Registration Act
1965, and the Countryside and Rights of Way Act 2000 which entitled walking on all those commons which
previously had no access, subject to certain restrictions. The Open Spaces Society could record and protect many
commons, including wetlands, despite opposition from the government and the real estate–builders lobby.
   Commons appropriated during colonial and imperialist times were returned to indigenous people right across
the globe. This got a fillip in 1992—500 years after Columbus landed in the ‘new world’—due to concerted action
by alliances of indigenous people at all levels, and a misguided attempt by Europeans to ‘celebrate’ the event that
                                                                The living commons: A historical understanding; page [10]
                                                                         Anita Cheria and Edwin; office@openspace.org.in
still was a raw wound for the Africans and the native Americans. Land and resources were returned to indigenous
people from Canada to Norway to Australia and New Zealand, in one of the largest decolonisation moves after the
1950s. Even India enacted Panchayat Raj (Extension to Scheduled Areas) Act (PESA) in 1996, followed by the
Scheduled Tribes and Other Traditional Forest Dwellers (Recognition of Forest Rights) Act 2006, popularly called
the Forest Rights Act (FRA).
    New commons, and a new understanding of the commons, are emerging to support the survival of the
commoners, quite distinct from the digital commons which occupies the ‘new commons’ space in the commons
discourse. The new commons in the Indian context is a result of a series of policy changes that have come up as a
response to community struggles for survival and dignity. They are an attempt to recognise and ensure certain
basic rights for marginalised communities as well as more responsive state functioning. In India there are, and
have been, strong movements to ensure recommoning—that the fences are brought down and the enclosures
opened up. The anti-caste movement is one such. The women’s movement and that of the sexual minorities are
others. What is new is that they are now being institutionalised with constitutional and legal support. The Right to
Information Act, RTI, 2005, (recommoning information) which provides transparency in the use of public
resources, the National Rural Employment Guarantee Act (recommoning the benefits of the use of national
wealth) and the Right to Education Act 2010 which provides for free and compulsory education to all children
aged six to fourteen (recommoning knowledge, tearing down the walls of caste and economic privilege), despite
flaws, lay a strong foundation for a new commons-led society. Others, such as the FRA, recognise existing
commons and attempt to correct historical injustice by returning land and resources to the communities. In fact,
these ‘commons’ were fenced off for so long and so effective was prohibition, that these are ‘new’ commons for
the majority of women, Dalits, Adivasi and children.
    In addition, there are a series of Supreme Court orders that recognise silence and natural and mineral resources
—including electromagnetic spectrum—as commons that can be privatised only for public utility, and even so for
a limited period. The Right to Food campaign is another ongoing process in the same direction that still needs to
find an appropriate language of rights, policy and implementation.
    The law recognises that fencing is only temporary—hence the time limit for patents and copyrights—and that
commons are the norm. In 2012, the Supreme Court of India allowed compulsory licensing of an anti–cancer drug
—slashing the price of the drug by 97%! The legal framework for returning the commons to the commoners, and
restoring the primacy of the commons in the constitutional framework is well underway.
    In international law, parts of Antarctica are recognised as global commons. So are most of the oceans but for 12
nautical miles from the coastline as ‘territorial waters’. There is right of passage in the 200 nautical mile exclusive
economic zones. All of outer space is considered common to humanity (rather arrogant of the human race—since
even the Earth is not exclusively a ‘human’ commons). This is in stark contrast to the earlier wave of discovery
when the Royal Charters were exclusively for colonising non-Christian lands. Perhaps this is belated
acknowledgement of the futility of the concept of terra nullius. Though there are stray attempts from private actors
to fence/lay claim to outer space with the possible emergence of technology that would enable such fencing, as of
now the international (human) law recognises it as commons.
5.2 A new knowledge base
   The International Association for the Study of Commons (IASC) was founded in 1989 as an interdisciplinary
knowledge sharing community. Through academically rigorous research, sharing of findings and their biennial
conferences, it could convincingly prove, in economic terms, the utility of the commons. Elinor Ostrom, a
political scientist, got the Economics Nobel for her effort in 2009. This increased interest on the commons, and
moved it from being at the bottom of the academic hierarchy, as interdisciplinary studies normally are.
   The United Nations Development Programme (UNDP) Senior Economist Mahbub ul Haq developed the
Human Development Index and Report in 1990, together with Amartya Sen in contrast to the World Bank that
brought out the World Development Report. GINI and other indices to measure inequality and wellbeing were
invented. At about the same time, there was an explosion of interest in ‘the rights of mother earth’ and the
Bolivarian revolution. The knowledge economy made the fatal flaws in tools of measurement of the industrial era
painfully evident. Governments commissioned better measures of development.
   The ‘mass’ nature of technology and business models, especially the internet and mobile telephony, opened up
a lot of space. While a security and privacy threat, paradoxically, this very same medium offers privacy and a level
playing field to some of the most excluded sections. Sexual minorities excluded from the physical commons have

                                                                 The living commons: A historical understanding; page [11]
                                                                          Anita Cheria and Edwin; office@openspace.org.in
found a haven in the virtual anonymity of cyberspace, though law enforcement and moral police turn the
anonymity to their advantage by using fake IDs to out identities.
   The very anti–thesis of the restrictive IPR regimes is the copyleft movement that has come up with ‘creative
commons’ with its own standards and licensing. Even capital needs the creativity of FOSS (Free Open Source
Software), leading to the paradox of multi–billion dollar software companies financing the Free Software
Foundation, implicitly acknowledging that the corporations (closes) need the creativity of ‘crowd computing’
(commons) and that non–monetary incentives are superior creativity enablers. Wikipedia, built totally with free
contributions, is way and above all other encyclopaedia both in terms of absolute volume and the breadth of
knowledge and matches them in accuracy despite being ‘open’. 3 It is also the most up–to–date of them all, being
online and being constantly updated.
   While practices of copyright and patenting continue for some kinds of knowledge systems, creative commons
licensing and a growing free software movement are now mainstream. The share of generic drugs in health care is
growing, giving the disease industry a run for their money. The Wikipedia and its various forms show ample
evidence of the benefits, wide acceptance and support for commoning. Creative commons are an
acknowledgement that knowledge creation is a social process. Freeing the airwaves, the use of free and open
source software (FOSS) and hardware are good beginnings.
   More universities—including ivy leaguers such as Princeton, Harvard and IGNOU—are putting out their
course material and research papers in open access, using the power of the internet, ‘commoning’ even more
knowledge without intermediaries or gatekeepers. Some even have free online courses—Udacity (Stanford), edX
(Harvard and Massachusetts Institute of Technology, MIT) and Coursera (Stanford, Princeton, University of
Pennsylvania, and University of Michigan). Udacity encourages collaborative learning among students, possibly
leading to cooperation by students in other spheres too. The Government of India has a policy of open access for
all publicly funded research. The open design movement includes even highly technical and specialised spheres
from computers to cars—from operating systems (Linux, Android) to hardware. Open discovery in health, brings
down research costs immeasurably.
5.3 The new economy
   There is a global shift from an economy based on scarcity to one of surplus. The global institutions of the state
and the market are yet to even know of the shift, let alone understand it. The global systems are designed for
appropriation and hoarding rather than distribution and sharing. The consequences are butter mountains and milk
lakes in Europe being dumped in the sea while there is famine in Africa. In India it has resulted in large-scale
rotting of food in godowns, while about half the children are malnourished.
   The commoners have responded by the freecycle and share economy, totally bypassing the market and
measurement indices. ‘Volunteerism’ has increased tremendously over the years, contributing skills and
competencies free of cost to the commons. Economic theory and measurement tools too caught up with reality,
understanding that the air is not empty nor an externality that can be the thrash can of the world, anymore than the
oceans are. Economists took a hard look at ‘externalities’ and devised better measures for corporations. National
and international laws, such as the Basel Convention on Hazardous Waste, seek to price in the entire cost of
ownership, including safe disposal, and make the manufacturer liable for the pollution caused by the ‘waste’ even
after the end of their product life. In this model, use of the global commons for dumping waste is priced in based
on the principle ‘the polluter pays’.
   In the heydays of capitalism, profits were privatised and the costs including pollution were socialised,
‘externalised’, right up to interstellar space. Contracts concerning precious natural resources were leased out on a
cost plus basis—as if the contractor was doing the community a favour rather than exploiting scarce natural
resources. Now the standards are different. Different regulatory bodies set the terms and conditions for service
provision (quality, pollution levels—no more an ‘externality’—and end user pricing). This is a better balance
between private enterprise and public service with a more equitable sharing of risk and reward on the one hand
and resources and equity on the other.
   There are some tentative steps towards ‘green accounting’ and ‘green budgeting’ so that the ‘national balance
sheet’ would reflect the use of irreplaceable natural resources and the commons and not treat them as externalities.
The economic indicator ‘gross domestic product’ or GDP is supplemented by national green accounts that would

3 Jim Giles, ‘Internet encyclopaedias go head to head’, Nature, vol. 438 no. 531 (15 December 2005), Note 4 Chapter 1 quoted by
  Tapscott D and Williams A D in Wikinomics. www.nature.com/news/2005/051212/full/438900a.html
                                                                          The living commons: A historical understanding; page [12]
                                                                                   Anita Cheria and Edwin; office@openspace.org.in
take natural capital use into account. The World Bank has developed the ‘adjusted net savings’ (ANS) which they
claim is a macro-level indicator of sustainable development that measures the ‘true rate of savings in an economy,
taking into account investment in human capital, depletion of natural resources and damage caused by pollution’.
ANS is a ‘national balance sheet’ by adding human capital accumulation and deducting natural resources losses.
Though a deeply flawed tool (its environmental impact measure does not even begin to capture the cost of global
warming), it is a step in the right direction by recognising the need to eliminate ‘externalities’.
   Though the green economy is a step forward from a sustainable economy, which was a step forward from the
‘enter-exploit-exit’ economy, it is still within the framework of ‘more of the same’—carbon trading, eco-
development—that led to the crisis in the first place. Better tools need to be developed, fully within the commons
framework.
5.4 To preserve and to protect: the challenges
   The commoners in Britain lost their first battle in stopping the enclosures, but found their space in governance
through the House of Commons, which now prevails over the House of Lords. This leads us to the first challenge
of the commons: The commoners need to be sovereign over their commons and have the capacity and willingness
to defend it. If not, then it is not their commons. If the community cannot preserve and protect their commons,
they will soon be alienated from it. The concept of independent village republics ‘gram swaraj’—the promise of
the Indian independence struggle—is based on this.
   A corollary is that these communities need to be internally just—inclusive and equitable—with increasing
space for self–expression. Communities that do not transform themselves to meet the new aspirations of their
constituents will soon find themselves disintegrating, their members drifting away and the commons wasting. The
mastery of the vocabulary of commons is often by the most regressive sections that seek to keep the commoners
away from the commons—in what is called the ‘elite capture’, of both the vocabulary and the commons. Thus the
second challenge to the commons is of building inclusive, equitable communities with equal access, benefits and
control, capable of defending the commons. Collectives of the invisible communities—of women, Dalits and
Adivasis, the disabled and the other disadvantaged—need to be built up so that they can enter into the commons
and into its governance. It means building inclusive and representative institutions of production, governance and
distribution in a manner that encourages and embraces diversity, difference and dissent. It is relatively easy in
small homogenous communities in a small, exclusive geo–political area over which it exercises sovereignty. It
becomes more challenging for complex social systems as we move from the micro level towards a ‘global village’
were ‘the community’ includes the richness of diversity. It is a tall order, but well within human capacity and
reach.
   An important rule is that the commons need commons. Commons need other commons to help sustain it—from
the physical to the knowledge to the socio–cultural and legal. None of the commons are standalones. The pastures
need the land, air and water to survive. Privatising any would lead to the destruction of the other commons. The
idea that ‘commons need commons’ covers not only the physical commons such as land, air and water, but also
the built commons.
   To defend the commons an alliance of communities is necessary. The World Social Forum is one such being
constructed at the global level. It is not monolithic and its organising principles are very different from the
traditional structures. Several regional and national level bodies exist or are in the process of being created. It is
important to note that commons is plural. There is a vast diversity within commons, their use, and regulation.
What we inherit is a multi–verse of commons across generations: a gift from the past, to be used for present needs,
and preserved for posterity. Alienation is not an option. If the vocabulary—formal or colloquial, written and oral
—does not support it, then the vocabulary must be grown to support it rather than restrict human endeavour due to
linguistic limitations.
   The state as an institution of property was, is, and always will be, hostile to the commons. This is true even, or
perhaps especially, when it uses the language of commons. As its capacity to enclose increases, it seeks to invade
and enclose as much of the commons as possible. It will then build arguments for legitimising such conquest. The
doctrine of ‘eminent domain’ is a Damocles sword hanging over the commons, which the state views as its
‘property–to–be–cleared of encroachments’. Any expectation that the state will protect the commons is naïve in
the extreme and akin to the fox guarding the chicken coop.
   The state appropriates the commons, displaces the people, destroys their livelihoods, and then magnanimously
returns a few crumbs as charity cloaked in the language of rights, entitlements and security—the ‘right’ to

                                                                 The living commons: A historical understanding; page [13]
                                                                          Anita Cheria and Edwin; office@openspace.org.in
education, employment scheme, and food ‘security’. Rather than this dependency creating charity, restoration of
the commons to the community, strengthening their sustainability, and enhancing their carrying capacity is the true
measure of rights and security. But the state, being an institution of property cannot do so, limited as it is by its
inherent characteristics and design as an instrument for the protection and promotion of property. It is for
communities to retake the commons, and then refashion them to egalitarian ends. The non–physical and the new
commons are important, since the concept of ‘control over the commons’ is fundamentally changed with the
development of new commons.
   There is a need for a clear understanding of the role of power, and power relations, with respect to commons.
Forcible commoning—internal colonisation—is a potent and ever present threat, whether by ethnic swamping, by
slow strangulation, or through religion and jingoistic nationalism. The institutions of property are the greatest
threats to the commons. Control of the state by corporations adds a disturbing new dimension. Addressing state
and non–state power is an important factor in protecting the commons. Since the state has claimed the sole right to
violence, neither it nor power can be ignored by any serious student or supporter of the commons. The present
institutions of the state are to protect property. Therefore, it is not the ‘capture of the state’ or its present
institutions that is important. These institutions can only protect property. To nurture the commons, a new kind of
institution, social organisation, socialisation and reproduction of knowledge—a different way of life itself—is
necessary.
   The state has used words to drown the voices. This happens when words are lost and divorced from the voices
that gave rise to them. One can certainly profit from mastering the words and the vocabulary, but real response
and change demands more than that. Since the economic restructuring of 1992, there have been some disastrous
efforts to privatise water, rivers and water supply. Large tracts of common land (pasture, mangroves, coast and
forest) have been invaded and fenced off literally and figuratively resulting in citizens movements forcing
temporary rollbacks. However, far from the media glare, active state intervention to dispossess the commoners
and indigenous people proceeds at a fast pace.
    It cannot be business as usual. Looking to business to evolve solutions, using the same tools by whatever label
—Clean Development Mechanism (CDM) or carbon trading—will only dig a deeper hole. This is one problem we
cannot spend our way out of. It requires a fundamental restructuring of society itself, going to the normative roots
and re–examining our belief systems. Groupthink will not suffice.
   The responsibility of civil society is to ensure equitable communities are in place to reclaim the commons. All
solutions cannot be expected to come only from the communities involved, and the civil society has a role to play
in the transition and evolution. Connecting and facilitating greater coordination among the movements for
restoration of the commons is a task that civil society is ideally positioned to do. Engaging and influencing the
lawmakers, developing the knowledge and skill sets around commons, helping communities build higher quality
of life through commons based livelihoods are other areas that civil society could consider. Engagement in
governance is anathema to civil society, but here again there are signs of hope. The Green Party and the Pirate
Party have the requisite base to get elected into the European Parliament and are present there.
5.5 The commons as an answer
   Still socialised in the Cartesian and dominance framework, there is a widespread belief that the commons is
external and it is often forgotten to include humans within them. But as the construct ‘House of Commons’ shows,
it was not always so. We have forgotten the fundamental unity of the commons, that ‘we are the living commons’.
   Strengthening commons institutions lie at the centre of any political and ecological solution. Traditional
institutional mechanisms and practices provide a starting point but a communitarian solution should be developed
based on the contemporary situation. New commons are constantly emerging and being recognised. They need to
be recognised and promoted with appropriate institutional mechanisms for their management and judicious use.
These need to be developed at many levels, in micro level village communities, at the meso– and macro–scale.
Change of power relations is the true benchmark of success.
   Building equitable, inclusive communities ensures that all are a part of the commons and that the commons can
actually be accessed by all the commoners. Today we are at the threshold of another major global shift. The
conditions of the previous shifts are well in place—the imperial overreach, an information revolution, and an
assertion of civil society. Collaboration and commons are the way to the future. It is not even a matter of if or
when. The change is already underway.
                                              —oO(end of document)Oo—

                                                                The living commons: A historical understanding; page [14]
                                                                         Anita Cheria and Edwin; office@openspace.org.in

More Related Content

What's hot

Imagining Buen Vivir
Imagining Buen VivirImagining Buen Vivir
Imagining Buen Vivir
Nicholas Anastasopoulos, PhD
 
Nicolaus Tideman: Resolving the Apparent Conflict between Land as Our Common ...
Nicolaus Tideman: Resolving the Apparent Conflict between Land as Our Common ...Nicolaus Tideman: Resolving the Apparent Conflict between Land as Our Common ...
Nicolaus Tideman: Resolving the Apparent Conflict between Land as Our Common ...
Moral Economy
 
Audiences are agents, not patients. Technoscientific citizenship today
Audiences are agents, not patients. Technoscientific citizenship todayAudiences are agents, not patients. Technoscientific citizenship today
Audiences are agents, not patients. Technoscientific citizenship today
Yurij Castelfranchi
 
Minority Population Analysis: The Aeta of the Philippines
Minority Population Analysis: The Aeta of the PhilippinesMinority Population Analysis: The Aeta of the Philippines
Minority Population Analysis: The Aeta of the Philippines
Olivier Serrat
 
Trisula of Kuningan
Trisula of KuninganTrisula of Kuningan
Trisula of Kuningan
fendi adiatmono
 
BOOK REVIEW
BOOK REVIEWBOOK REVIEW
BOOK REVIEW
Prakash Mallick
 
021
021021
Indigenous knowledge systems: Relevance for Just, Sustainable, Equitable World
Indigenous knowledge systems: Relevance for Just, Sustainable, Equitable World Indigenous knowledge systems: Relevance for Just, Sustainable, Equitable World
Indigenous knowledge systems: Relevance for Just, Sustainable, Equitable World
Ashish Kothari
 
Local development model (Vrs July 2015) (2)
Local  development model (Vrs July 2015) (2)Local  development model (Vrs July 2015) (2)
Local development model (Vrs July 2015) (2)
Aristarque Mendo Chirume
 
Governance of Conservation
Governance of ConservationGovernance of Conservation
Governance of Conservation
Ashish Kothari
 
Robert Aman. educating for decolonization
Robert Aman. educating for decolonizationRobert Aman. educating for decolonization
Robert Aman. educating for decolonization
5ncoal
 
Harmonization of inter-cultural inter-religious and inter-ethnic relations: t...
Harmonization of inter-cultural inter-religious and inter-ethnic relations: t...Harmonization of inter-cultural inter-religious and inter-ethnic relations: t...
Harmonization of inter-cultural inter-religious and inter-ethnic relations: t...
TANKO AHMED fwc
 
Well being, biodiversity, post-2015 agenda, by Ashish Kothari
Well being, biodiversity, post-2015 agenda, by Ashish KothariWell being, biodiversity, post-2015 agenda, by Ashish Kothari
Well being, biodiversity, post-2015 agenda, by Ashish Kothari
Ashish Kothari
 
Social Identity, Natural Resources, & Peacebuilding
Social Identity, Natural Resources, & PeacebuildingSocial Identity, Natural Resources, & Peacebuilding
Social Identity, Natural Resources, & Peacebuilding
CAPRi
 
Rights and Accountability in WASH (India) Arickal Dash and Gosling (revised)
Rights and Accountability in WASH (India) Arickal Dash and Gosling (revised)Rights and Accountability in WASH (India) Arickal Dash and Gosling (revised)
Rights and Accountability in WASH (India) Arickal Dash and Gosling (revised)
Binu Arickal
 
Revitalizing indigenous leadership
Revitalizing indigenous leadershipRevitalizing indigenous leadership
Revitalizing indigenous leadership
ifadseahub
 
Eco-swaraj: Radical Ecological Democracy towards Equity & Sustainability
Eco-swaraj: Radical Ecological Democracy towards Equity & Sustainability Eco-swaraj: Radical Ecological Democracy towards Equity & Sustainability
Eco-swaraj: Radical Ecological Democracy towards Equity & Sustainability
Ashish Kothari
 
Newmedia
NewmediaNewmedia
Newmedia
chloeyan
 
Com525 archanth
Com525 archanthCom525 archanth
Com525 archanth
chizzymoi
 
15.03.2015 (1)
15.03.2015 (1)15.03.2015 (1)
15.03.2015 (1)
Kathryn Mecrow
 

What's hot (20)

Imagining Buen Vivir
Imagining Buen VivirImagining Buen Vivir
Imagining Buen Vivir
 
Nicolaus Tideman: Resolving the Apparent Conflict between Land as Our Common ...
Nicolaus Tideman: Resolving the Apparent Conflict between Land as Our Common ...Nicolaus Tideman: Resolving the Apparent Conflict between Land as Our Common ...
Nicolaus Tideman: Resolving the Apparent Conflict between Land as Our Common ...
 
Audiences are agents, not patients. Technoscientific citizenship today
Audiences are agents, not patients. Technoscientific citizenship todayAudiences are agents, not patients. Technoscientific citizenship today
Audiences are agents, not patients. Technoscientific citizenship today
 
Minority Population Analysis: The Aeta of the Philippines
Minority Population Analysis: The Aeta of the PhilippinesMinority Population Analysis: The Aeta of the Philippines
Minority Population Analysis: The Aeta of the Philippines
 
Trisula of Kuningan
Trisula of KuninganTrisula of Kuningan
Trisula of Kuningan
 
BOOK REVIEW
BOOK REVIEWBOOK REVIEW
BOOK REVIEW
 
021
021021
021
 
Indigenous knowledge systems: Relevance for Just, Sustainable, Equitable World
Indigenous knowledge systems: Relevance for Just, Sustainable, Equitable World Indigenous knowledge systems: Relevance for Just, Sustainable, Equitable World
Indigenous knowledge systems: Relevance for Just, Sustainable, Equitable World
 
Local development model (Vrs July 2015) (2)
Local  development model (Vrs July 2015) (2)Local  development model (Vrs July 2015) (2)
Local development model (Vrs July 2015) (2)
 
Governance of Conservation
Governance of ConservationGovernance of Conservation
Governance of Conservation
 
Robert Aman. educating for decolonization
Robert Aman. educating for decolonizationRobert Aman. educating for decolonization
Robert Aman. educating for decolonization
 
Harmonization of inter-cultural inter-religious and inter-ethnic relations: t...
Harmonization of inter-cultural inter-religious and inter-ethnic relations: t...Harmonization of inter-cultural inter-religious and inter-ethnic relations: t...
Harmonization of inter-cultural inter-religious and inter-ethnic relations: t...
 
Well being, biodiversity, post-2015 agenda, by Ashish Kothari
Well being, biodiversity, post-2015 agenda, by Ashish KothariWell being, biodiversity, post-2015 agenda, by Ashish Kothari
Well being, biodiversity, post-2015 agenda, by Ashish Kothari
 
Social Identity, Natural Resources, & Peacebuilding
Social Identity, Natural Resources, & PeacebuildingSocial Identity, Natural Resources, & Peacebuilding
Social Identity, Natural Resources, & Peacebuilding
 
Rights and Accountability in WASH (India) Arickal Dash and Gosling (revised)
Rights and Accountability in WASH (India) Arickal Dash and Gosling (revised)Rights and Accountability in WASH (India) Arickal Dash and Gosling (revised)
Rights and Accountability in WASH (India) Arickal Dash and Gosling (revised)
 
Revitalizing indigenous leadership
Revitalizing indigenous leadershipRevitalizing indigenous leadership
Revitalizing indigenous leadership
 
Eco-swaraj: Radical Ecological Democracy towards Equity & Sustainability
Eco-swaraj: Radical Ecological Democracy towards Equity & Sustainability Eco-swaraj: Radical Ecological Democracy towards Equity & Sustainability
Eco-swaraj: Radical Ecological Democracy towards Equity & Sustainability
 
Newmedia
NewmediaNewmedia
Newmedia
 
Com525 archanth
Com525 archanthCom525 archanth
Com525 archanth
 
15.03.2015 (1)
15.03.2015 (1)15.03.2015 (1)
15.03.2015 (1)
 

Viewers also liked

Welcome to the Collections Trust
Welcome to the Collections TrustWelcome to the Collections Trust
Welcome to the Collections Trust
Nicholas Poole
 
United we Stand
United we StandUnited we Stand
United we Stand
Nicholas Poole
 
Accreditation and the New Collections Management
Accreditation and the New Collections ManagementAccreditation and the New Collections Management
Accreditation and the New Collections Management
Nicholas Poole
 
Social Media for Reconstructing Communities in Tension
Social Media for Reconstructing Communities in TensionSocial Media for Reconstructing Communities in Tension
Social Media for Reconstructing Communities in Tension
Marlon Parker
 
Future Collections
Future CollectionsFuture Collections
Future Collections
Nicholas Poole
 
Digital Libraries and Europe
Digital Libraries and EuropeDigital Libraries and Europe
Digital Libraries and Europe
Nicholas Poole
 
Great Museums need Great Management
Great Museums need Great ManagementGreat Museums need Great Management
Great Museums need Great Management
Nicholas Poole
 
Mobile Phones in Africa
Mobile Phones in AfricaMobile Phones in Africa
Mobile Phones in Africa
Marlon Parker
 

Viewers also liked (8)

Welcome to the Collections Trust
Welcome to the Collections TrustWelcome to the Collections Trust
Welcome to the Collections Trust
 
United we Stand
United we StandUnited we Stand
United we Stand
 
Accreditation and the New Collections Management
Accreditation and the New Collections ManagementAccreditation and the New Collections Management
Accreditation and the New Collections Management
 
Social Media for Reconstructing Communities in Tension
Social Media for Reconstructing Communities in TensionSocial Media for Reconstructing Communities in Tension
Social Media for Reconstructing Communities in Tension
 
Future Collections
Future CollectionsFuture Collections
Future Collections
 
Digital Libraries and Europe
Digital Libraries and EuropeDigital Libraries and Europe
Digital Libraries and Europe
 
Great Museums need Great Management
Great Museums need Great ManagementGreat Museums need Great Management
Great Museums need Great Management
 
Mobile Phones in Africa
Mobile Phones in AfricaMobile Phones in Africa
Mobile Phones in Africa
 

Similar to The Living Commons A Historical Understanding

Moritz Museums International "Partnerships in the Commons"
Moritz Museums International "Partnerships in the Commons"Moritz Museums International "Partnerships in the Commons"
Moritz Museums International "Partnerships in the Commons"
Tom Moritz
 
Bio diversity and_indian_society
Bio diversity and_indian_societyBio diversity and_indian_society
Bio diversity and_indian_society
JAIDEEP CHATTERJEE
 
Bio_diversity_and_Indian_society
Bio_diversity_and_Indian_societyBio_diversity_and_Indian_society
Bio_diversity_and_Indian_society
JAIDEEP CHATTERJEE
 
The Teacher´s Guide_Introduction_Worldview_Dimension
The Teacher´s Guide_Introduction_Worldview_DimensionThe Teacher´s Guide_Introduction_Worldview_Dimension
The Teacher´s Guide_Introduction_Worldview_Dimension
Gaia Education
 
Rownowaga 1 uk-8-15
Rownowaga 1 uk-8-15Rownowaga 1 uk-8-15
Rownowaga 1 uk-8-15
Małopolski Instytut Kultury
 
The Age of Plenty and Leisure: Essays for a New Principle of Organization in ...
The Age of Plenty and Leisure: Essays for a New Principle of Organization in ...The Age of Plenty and Leisure: Essays for a New Principle of Organization in ...
The Age of Plenty and Leisure: Essays for a New Principle of Organization in ...
Luke Barnesmoore o
 
Liu Lingzhi LiuEAD IIPaul Hufker September 16th Universa.docx
Liu Lingzhi LiuEAD IIPaul Hufker September 16th Universa.docxLiu Lingzhi LiuEAD IIPaul Hufker September 16th Universa.docx
Liu Lingzhi LiuEAD IIPaul Hufker September 16th Universa.docx
croysierkathey
 
CESCoooooooooooooooooooooooooooooo-2.pdf
CESCoooooooooooooooooooooooooooooo-2.pdfCESCoooooooooooooooooooooooooooooo-2.pdf
CESCoooooooooooooooooooooooooooooo-2.pdf
NonSy1
 
The importance of tangible and intangible cultural heritage
The importance of tangible and intangible cultural heritageThe importance of tangible and intangible cultural heritage
The importance of tangible and intangible cultural heritage
AleAlvarez27
 
Cultural Appropriation In Anthropology
Cultural Appropriation In AnthropologyCultural Appropriation In Anthropology
Cultural Appropriation In Anthropology
Carla Bennington
 
Outlines on environmental philosophy part 9
Outlines on environmental philosophy   part 9Outlines on environmental philosophy   part 9
Outlines on environmental philosophy part 9
Steven Ghezzo
 
Humans and the environmentLECTURE 1Environment and P.docx
Humans and the environmentLECTURE 1Environment and P.docxHumans and the environmentLECTURE 1Environment and P.docx
Humans and the environmentLECTURE 1Environment and P.docx
sheronlewthwaite
 
Ecojustice and Mythology
Ecojustice and MythologyEcojustice and Mythology
Ecojustice and Mythology
Central Connecticut State University
 
Value Education and Human Rights
Value Education and Human RightsValue Education and Human Rights
Value Education and Human Rights
Ketan Agrawal
 
Anth1 Culture
Anth1 CultureAnth1 Culture
Anth1 Culture
Jana Fortier
 
The two faces of the commons
The two faces of the commonsThe two faces of the commons
The two faces of the commons
CIFOR-ICRAF
 
Nov8 ful liearn2012hexagonvii -2
Nov8 ful liearn2012hexagonvii -2Nov8 ful liearn2012hexagonvii -2
Nov8 ful liearn2012hexagonvii -2
eericksoncook
 
Laudato si 4 integral ecology
Laudato si 4 integral ecologyLaudato si 4 integral ecology
Laudato si 4 integral ecology
Martin M Flynn
 
1The EconomyAn economy is a system of production, dist.docx
1The EconomyAn economy is a system of production, dist.docx1The EconomyAn economy is a system of production, dist.docx
1The EconomyAn economy is a system of production, dist.docx
eugeniadean34240
 
Assignment on culture
Assignment on cultureAssignment on culture
Assignment on culture
KAZAL CHANDRA BARMAN
 

Similar to The Living Commons A Historical Understanding (20)

Moritz Museums International "Partnerships in the Commons"
Moritz Museums International "Partnerships in the Commons"Moritz Museums International "Partnerships in the Commons"
Moritz Museums International "Partnerships in the Commons"
 
Bio diversity and_indian_society
Bio diversity and_indian_societyBio diversity and_indian_society
Bio diversity and_indian_society
 
Bio_diversity_and_Indian_society
Bio_diversity_and_Indian_societyBio_diversity_and_Indian_society
Bio_diversity_and_Indian_society
 
The Teacher´s Guide_Introduction_Worldview_Dimension
The Teacher´s Guide_Introduction_Worldview_DimensionThe Teacher´s Guide_Introduction_Worldview_Dimension
The Teacher´s Guide_Introduction_Worldview_Dimension
 
Rownowaga 1 uk-8-15
Rownowaga 1 uk-8-15Rownowaga 1 uk-8-15
Rownowaga 1 uk-8-15
 
The Age of Plenty and Leisure: Essays for a New Principle of Organization in ...
The Age of Plenty and Leisure: Essays for a New Principle of Organization in ...The Age of Plenty and Leisure: Essays for a New Principle of Organization in ...
The Age of Plenty and Leisure: Essays for a New Principle of Organization in ...
 
Liu Lingzhi LiuEAD IIPaul Hufker September 16th Universa.docx
Liu Lingzhi LiuEAD IIPaul Hufker September 16th Universa.docxLiu Lingzhi LiuEAD IIPaul Hufker September 16th Universa.docx
Liu Lingzhi LiuEAD IIPaul Hufker September 16th Universa.docx
 
CESCoooooooooooooooooooooooooooooo-2.pdf
CESCoooooooooooooooooooooooooooooo-2.pdfCESCoooooooooooooooooooooooooooooo-2.pdf
CESCoooooooooooooooooooooooooooooo-2.pdf
 
The importance of tangible and intangible cultural heritage
The importance of tangible and intangible cultural heritageThe importance of tangible and intangible cultural heritage
The importance of tangible and intangible cultural heritage
 
Cultural Appropriation In Anthropology
Cultural Appropriation In AnthropologyCultural Appropriation In Anthropology
Cultural Appropriation In Anthropology
 
Outlines on environmental philosophy part 9
Outlines on environmental philosophy   part 9Outlines on environmental philosophy   part 9
Outlines on environmental philosophy part 9
 
Humans and the environmentLECTURE 1Environment and P.docx
Humans and the environmentLECTURE 1Environment and P.docxHumans and the environmentLECTURE 1Environment and P.docx
Humans and the environmentLECTURE 1Environment and P.docx
 
Ecojustice and Mythology
Ecojustice and MythologyEcojustice and Mythology
Ecojustice and Mythology
 
Value Education and Human Rights
Value Education and Human RightsValue Education and Human Rights
Value Education and Human Rights
 
Anth1 Culture
Anth1 CultureAnth1 Culture
Anth1 Culture
 
The two faces of the commons
The two faces of the commonsThe two faces of the commons
The two faces of the commons
 
Nov8 ful liearn2012hexagonvii -2
Nov8 ful liearn2012hexagonvii -2Nov8 ful liearn2012hexagonvii -2
Nov8 ful liearn2012hexagonvii -2
 
Laudato si 4 integral ecology
Laudato si 4 integral ecologyLaudato si 4 integral ecology
Laudato si 4 integral ecology
 
1The EconomyAn economy is a system of production, dist.docx
1The EconomyAn economy is a system of production, dist.docx1The EconomyAn economy is a system of production, dist.docx
1The EconomyAn economy is a system of production, dist.docx
 
Assignment on culture
Assignment on cultureAssignment on culture
Assignment on culture
 

More from OpenSpace

SC/ST (PoA) Act Monitoring at the state level
SC/ST (PoA) Act Monitoring at the state levelSC/ST (PoA) Act Monitoring at the state level
SC/ST (PoA) Act Monitoring at the state level
OpenSpace
 
SC/ST (PoA) Case monitoring formats
SC/ST (PoA) Case monitoring formatsSC/ST (PoA) Case monitoring formats
SC/ST (PoA) Case monitoring formats
OpenSpace
 
SC/ST POA Amendment 2013
SC/ST POA Amendment 2013SC/ST POA Amendment 2013
SC/ST POA Amendment 2013
OpenSpace
 
POA 3a Relief Norms Notification 2014
POA 3a Relief Norms Notification 2014POA 3a Relief Norms Notification 2014
POA 3a Relief Norms Notification 2014
OpenSpace
 
Swachch bharat
Swachch bharatSwachch bharat
Swachch bharat
OpenSpace
 
POA 1b SCs and STs (Prevention of Atrocities) Amendment Ordinance 2014
POA 1b SCs and STs (Prevention of Atrocities) Amendment Ordinance 2014POA 1b SCs and STs (Prevention of Atrocities) Amendment Ordinance 2014
POA 1b SCs and STs (Prevention of Atrocities) Amendment Ordinance 2014
OpenSpace
 
SCST (PoA) Implementation in Karnataka status report 2013
SCST (PoA) Implementation in Karnataka status report 2013SCST (PoA) Implementation in Karnataka status report 2013
SCST (PoA) Implementation in Karnataka status report 2013
OpenSpace
 
SCST (PoA) Implementation in Karnataka status report 2013 (Kannada)
SCST (PoA) Implementation in Karnataka status report 2013 (Kannada) SCST (PoA) Implementation in Karnataka status report 2013 (Kannada)
SCST (PoA) Implementation in Karnataka status report 2013 (Kannada)
OpenSpace
 
SCST (PoA) Implementation in Karnataka status report 2013 cover initial pages...
SCST (PoA) Implementation in Karnataka status report 2013 cover initial pages...SCST (PoA) Implementation in Karnataka status report 2013 cover initial pages...
SCST (PoA) Implementation in Karnataka status report 2013 cover initial pages...
OpenSpace
 
SCST (PoA) Implementation in Karnataka status report 2013 cover
SCST (PoA) Implementation in Karnataka status report 2013 coverSCST (PoA) Implementation in Karnataka status report 2013 cover
SCST (PoA) Implementation in Karnataka status report 2013 cover
OpenSpace
 
Violence against women garment workers, gender subordination in India
Violence against women garment workers, gender subordination in IndiaViolence against women garment workers, gender subordination in India
Violence against women garment workers, gender subordination in India
OpenSpace
 
POA 9 Karnataka state police manual (DCRE)
POA 9 Karnataka state police manual (DCRE)POA 9 Karnataka state police manual (DCRE)
POA 9 Karnataka state police manual (DCRE)
OpenSpace
 
POA 8 DVMC roles and responsibilities
POA 8 DVMC roles and responsibilitiesPOA 8 DVMC roles and responsibilities
POA 8 DVMC roles and responsibilities
OpenSpace
 
POA 7 How to give evidence in court
POA 7 How to give evidence in courtPOA 7 How to give evidence in court
POA 7 How to give evidence in court
OpenSpace
 
POA 6 POA and IPC sections
POA 6 POA and IPC sectionsPOA 6 POA and IPC sections
POA 6 POA and IPC sections
OpenSpace
 
POA 5b Monitoring calendar (detailed)
POA 5b Monitoring calendar (detailed)POA 5b Monitoring calendar (detailed)
POA 5b Monitoring calendar (detailed)
OpenSpace
 
POA 5a Monitoring calendar (Single Page)
POA 5a Monitoring calendar (Single Page)POA 5a Monitoring calendar (Single Page)
POA 5a Monitoring calendar (Single Page)
OpenSpace
 
POA 3b Ambedkar foundation relief for heinous crimes
POA 3b Ambedkar foundation relief for heinous crimesPOA 3b Ambedkar foundation relief for heinous crimes
POA 3b Ambedkar foundation relief for heinous crimes
OpenSpace
 
POA 3a Relief norms notification 2011
POA 3a Relief norms notification 2011POA 3a Relief norms notification 2011
POA 3a Relief norms notification 2011
OpenSpace
 
POA 2 SCs and STs (PoA) Rules 1995
POA 2 SCs and STs (PoA) Rules 1995POA 2 SCs and STs (PoA) Rules 1995
POA 2 SCs and STs (PoA) Rules 1995
OpenSpace
 

More from OpenSpace (20)

SC/ST (PoA) Act Monitoring at the state level
SC/ST (PoA) Act Monitoring at the state levelSC/ST (PoA) Act Monitoring at the state level
SC/ST (PoA) Act Monitoring at the state level
 
SC/ST (PoA) Case monitoring formats
SC/ST (PoA) Case monitoring formatsSC/ST (PoA) Case monitoring formats
SC/ST (PoA) Case monitoring formats
 
SC/ST POA Amendment 2013
SC/ST POA Amendment 2013SC/ST POA Amendment 2013
SC/ST POA Amendment 2013
 
POA 3a Relief Norms Notification 2014
POA 3a Relief Norms Notification 2014POA 3a Relief Norms Notification 2014
POA 3a Relief Norms Notification 2014
 
Swachch bharat
Swachch bharatSwachch bharat
Swachch bharat
 
POA 1b SCs and STs (Prevention of Atrocities) Amendment Ordinance 2014
POA 1b SCs and STs (Prevention of Atrocities) Amendment Ordinance 2014POA 1b SCs and STs (Prevention of Atrocities) Amendment Ordinance 2014
POA 1b SCs and STs (Prevention of Atrocities) Amendment Ordinance 2014
 
SCST (PoA) Implementation in Karnataka status report 2013
SCST (PoA) Implementation in Karnataka status report 2013SCST (PoA) Implementation in Karnataka status report 2013
SCST (PoA) Implementation in Karnataka status report 2013
 
SCST (PoA) Implementation in Karnataka status report 2013 (Kannada)
SCST (PoA) Implementation in Karnataka status report 2013 (Kannada) SCST (PoA) Implementation in Karnataka status report 2013 (Kannada)
SCST (PoA) Implementation in Karnataka status report 2013 (Kannada)
 
SCST (PoA) Implementation in Karnataka status report 2013 cover initial pages...
SCST (PoA) Implementation in Karnataka status report 2013 cover initial pages...SCST (PoA) Implementation in Karnataka status report 2013 cover initial pages...
SCST (PoA) Implementation in Karnataka status report 2013 cover initial pages...
 
SCST (PoA) Implementation in Karnataka status report 2013 cover
SCST (PoA) Implementation in Karnataka status report 2013 coverSCST (PoA) Implementation in Karnataka status report 2013 cover
SCST (PoA) Implementation in Karnataka status report 2013 cover
 
Violence against women garment workers, gender subordination in India
Violence against women garment workers, gender subordination in IndiaViolence against women garment workers, gender subordination in India
Violence against women garment workers, gender subordination in India
 
POA 9 Karnataka state police manual (DCRE)
POA 9 Karnataka state police manual (DCRE)POA 9 Karnataka state police manual (DCRE)
POA 9 Karnataka state police manual (DCRE)
 
POA 8 DVMC roles and responsibilities
POA 8 DVMC roles and responsibilitiesPOA 8 DVMC roles and responsibilities
POA 8 DVMC roles and responsibilities
 
POA 7 How to give evidence in court
POA 7 How to give evidence in courtPOA 7 How to give evidence in court
POA 7 How to give evidence in court
 
POA 6 POA and IPC sections
POA 6 POA and IPC sectionsPOA 6 POA and IPC sections
POA 6 POA and IPC sections
 
POA 5b Monitoring calendar (detailed)
POA 5b Monitoring calendar (detailed)POA 5b Monitoring calendar (detailed)
POA 5b Monitoring calendar (detailed)
 
POA 5a Monitoring calendar (Single Page)
POA 5a Monitoring calendar (Single Page)POA 5a Monitoring calendar (Single Page)
POA 5a Monitoring calendar (Single Page)
 
POA 3b Ambedkar foundation relief for heinous crimes
POA 3b Ambedkar foundation relief for heinous crimesPOA 3b Ambedkar foundation relief for heinous crimes
POA 3b Ambedkar foundation relief for heinous crimes
 
POA 3a Relief norms notification 2011
POA 3a Relief norms notification 2011POA 3a Relief norms notification 2011
POA 3a Relief norms notification 2011
 
POA 2 SCs and STs (PoA) Rules 1995
POA 2 SCs and STs (PoA) Rules 1995POA 2 SCs and STs (PoA) Rules 1995
POA 2 SCs and STs (PoA) Rules 1995
 

The Living Commons A Historical Understanding

  • 1. The living commons: A historical understanding Anita Cheria and Edwin1 1 Introduction A prerequisite to understanding the commons, its use, and governance is an understanding of the power relations with respect to commons. Power is accentuated by knowledge in action (technology). The restricted socialisation of knowledge and the control of technology have vastly enhanced the ability to enclose, and therefore actual enclosure of, the commons. The history of commons can be traced as a continuing effort of retaining or reclaiming the commons by the commoners on the one side, and efforts at enclosure and encroachment by the dominant on the other. The role of knowledge and technology is critical, since they accentuate the nature of society that underlies it. Knowledge is organised so that it produces such technology that makes an equitable society more equitable, and an oppressive one more oppressive. While knowledge systems such as language and ideology provide the inspiration, moral and intellectual superstructure, technology provides the actual means and tools, empowering humans far beyond their fragile bodies, almost to the extent of their dreams. Understanding the history of enclosures of the physical commons, the fencing of knowledge, and the keen attempts to re–common them is to take the journey through the centuries, deeply aware of the nature of power and production relations. It has been a constant seesaw, with the commoners opening up new spaces, reclaiming the commons while the enclosers, who control the state, find newer ways of enclosure and rent. This note looks at the historical developments and the emerging opportunities. 2 What do we mean by commons The traditional commons were the spaces of the powerless, of the people who do not have ‘private spaces’ whether for livelihood or leisure. Intimately entwined with their life, these spaces abounded with life, culture, and tradition. A sacred grove was not empty, but a place where their ancestral spirits still walked, had medicinal plants, and was inextricably intertwined with their knowledge, their identity, and their very being. Each bit of the ‘empty’ space had a special resonance, each being sentient with the spirits of the trees, plants, and the inanimate. The commons can be classified as two, the natural commons and the built commons. The natural commons are the land, water, air, and their combinations such as the forest, seas, and rivers inclusive of the life in them. It includes on (land, sea, forests, rivers), above (air, space) and under (minerals, oil, and natural gas) the ground. With the progress of science, newer commons are being identified such as electromagnetic spectrum and space itself. Silence is a recognised common now, in 2012, with noise regulation and pollution rules in place, though it seemed an outlandish idea when Ivan Ilich suggested it in 1982. The built commons are two—the hardcoms and the softcoms. The ‘hard’ commons, ‘hardcoms’, are the physical livelihood systems such as infrastructure built with public resources. Examples of built commons are the crèches, schools, roads, government buildings such as village offices, post offices, public toilets, and primary health centres. The hardcoms have a knowledge superstructure. Knowledge spans culture, religion, tradition and law on the one hand, and information, science, and technology on the other. These are the ‘soft’ part of the built commons, or the ‘softcoms’. This superstructure is the ‘software’ or the ‘softcoms’ govern the use of hardcoms. The softcoms determine inclusion, exclusion, access, benefit, and control. Commons are managed and shared by a community that is willing and able to defend it. In the mapping and subsequent fencing of natural resources, the powerful took over the best part and enclosed it for their exclusive use. The rest shared the commons and were the commoners who formed the community. The powerful (the rich) have always had their ‘private’ resource base. It is only the powerless (variously called the ‘commons’, the ‘commoners’ or the ‘poor’)2 who were excluded from property, who use spaces ‘in common’ to ensure the minimum critical mass of space for viability to ensure their own survival. Commons are an attempt to have a viable resource base by collective usage and stewardship where the laws of property (the ‘formal legal system’) breakdown. In the modern world too, the phenomenon called ‘secession of the successful’ is seen where the 1 Anita and Edwin are directors of OpenSpace, a human rights and development think tank. The authors thank the Commons Initiative, Foundation for Ecological Security, for the many discussions on the commons that helped sharpen concepts and deepen understanding. This paper was presented at the National Consultation on Commons, New Delhi, 20-21 April 2012 2 Poverty is a factor of power, not production. For an analysis of the intimate links between poverty and power see M K Bhat, et al Life Goes On… 1999, and Anita Cheria et al A Human Rights Approach to Development 2004. The living commons: A historical understanding; page [1] Anita Cheria and Edwin; office@openspace.org.in
  • 2. powerful acquire as much territory as possible and fence themselves in ‘gated communities’. We have not evolved as much as we would like to believe. Commons does not always mean open, unrestricted access for all. Visualising ‘the commons’ is often a romantic imaging of natural resources, most often meadows, rivers, mountains, and forests in their pristine state. There is a utopian image of them being open access, used without destruction, and always uncontaminated, not ‘despoiled’ by human interference. Human presence, if at all present, is that of the ‘noble savage’. The reality is a little more complex. These ‘commons’ have been regulated, access restricted and even prohibited, based on gender, age, faith/belief, caste, or ethnic origin. The ‘commons’ were, and are, rigorously defined in access, benefits, and control. Significant sections of society are kept out on the basis of caste, gender, or age. The process of reclaiming the ‘commons’ needs to move beyond utopian imaging to an inclusive framework. At the same time, the rights to the commons translate into the right to use, the right of security to tenure, and the right to stewardship —very different from the concept of ‘ownership’ of ‘property’ that the law understands, and tries to foist upon communities in the name of joint and community title deeds (patta, khata). Increasingly the terminology of ‘commons’ is used by the dominant to claim the right to what are essentially the ‘commons of the poor’ for resource extraction and waste disposal. This forcible commoning is nothing but resource capture after the dominant have destroyed their ‘property’. It is no coincidence that biodiversity is richest in ‘underdeveloped’ areas, and that ‘developed’ areas are monoculture deserts. It is no coincidence either, that the indigenous people resist this invasion of their commons, or that there are literally thousands of struggles when the state tries to invade and occupy the commons of the poor by terming them ‘national’ commons. The west, unsurprisingly, calls these as ‘global’ commons and plans to use them as carbon sinks and other forms of waste absorbers or the indigenous knowledge—very much a part of knowledge and creative commons—as ‘raw material’ for their intellectual ‘property’. The health of the commons is intrinsically linked to the health of the community and the health of every commoner in such a tight correlation that one cannot exist without the other. Commons play a strategic role in maintaining ecological health, reducing poverty, and improving collective action. Those who want to destroy a community destroy their commons and those who want to destroy the commons destroy their community. One is a prerequisite for the other. As long as a community willing and able to defend its commons exists, that commons will survive. 3 The importance of vocabulary 3.1 Commons and vocabulary There is a world of difference between the commons and common property. Though abbreviated as CPR, common pool resources are very different from common property regimes. The blurring of this distinction, sometimes inadvertent but oftentimes deliberate, has led to many avoidable conflicts, the displacement and alienation of the commoner from the commons, and the loss of the commons itself. ‘Commons’ is outside the property framework, while ‘public property’ is within the property framework— islands within private property. In legal terms, commons would be res communes, property that is public due to its very nature, while public property would be res publicae belonging and open to the public by virtue of law. In parts of India (Rajasthan, Punjab and Haryana), Samlat/Samlati from ‘shamlat’ is still used widely in village common law. The term had its origins in the Mughal era Urdu/Farsi term ‘shamil’ meaning to include (in Arabic ‘comprehensive’, ‘inclusive’, ‘universal’ and even ‘perfect’). ‘Shamilat’ approximates to ‘inclusive’ or ‘shared’, both of which are core values of the commons. The ‘Sambhar Shamlat’ is a revenue arrangement for the salt lake of Sambhar instituted jointly by the kingdoms of Jaipur and Jodhpur in pre–British India. In Tamilnadu, the term Poramboke is used. There is an intimate linkage between the language used to describe the commons and the perception and use of commons—how ‘the commons’ have been translated from practice to restrictive usage. The reduction of thought to ideas, ideas to concepts to language and then to words, speech, and writing results in transmission loss at every stage. Though languages by themselves are not deterministic, they do have a certain bias in that direction. The words used to describe become words used to determine. This determinism becomes even more pronounced when translated into the written form of the language and then to law. When translated into law which determines action, it results in linguistic deficiencies restricting action—a serious lacuna which impedes progress on protection, use and benefits of the commons. What is written becomes the legal limit. Just as language has been used to bind, it can just as usefully be employed to liberate the commons and return it to the commoners and the The living commons: A historical understanding; page [2] Anita Cheria and Edwin; office@openspace.org.in
  • 3. community. The vocabulary of the law is the vocabulary of property. The conflict between the law and those who break it is often the conflict between the deterministic nature of the written word and the descriptive intent. 3.2 Socio–linguistics: The vocabulary of property and industrial society Words reveal the nature of society, social relations, and even offer clues to their physical environment. For instance, languages of tropical lands have few words for snow, while the Eskimo have more than a dozen. If the language of a society embeds space with life, with animals, plants, and the inanimate, then ‘development’ in the language of that society would not cut through the migration paths of animals or fence their waterholes. Unfortunately, the dominant paradigm privileges industry and capital. The industrial revolution gave rise to capitalism and democracy. The jurisprudence that developed at the time gave rise to its own vocabulary with industrial relations as the normative. The vocabulary of individual private property and individual rights developed co–terminus with science, industrialisation, capitalism and democracy. In a rather frank statement of its objectives, industry tells us that ‘development’ is to ‘exploit’ natural resources. Efficiency is to do it in the fastest time possible. Anything that does not directly affect their bottom line, or what they can get away with—for instance dumping pollution into the air and water—was not counted as a ‘cost’ but as an ‘externality’ by which they could maximise book profits. The language of commons is to protect natural resources. Efficiency is to minimise the resource use footprint. Greenfield is very different from green field—spaces make a lot of difference in language too! The present vocabulary developed as a vocabulary of private property since commons was the norm and implicit. Property was a subset of the commons. The king owned all else. (It is from the ‘royal’ or ‘regal’ estates that we have the term ‘real’ estate.) At the time ‘wastes’ meant any uninhabited land, and what are private fields today were called ‘closes’. There needed to be terms to distinguish property from the commons, since property was a subset of the commons. Unfortunately, the language of property has become so dominant that there is a role reversal, and in extreme cases there is even denial of commons due to absence of explicit definition or description. Wastes were places where there were no people. This land did not produce tax. Though there is a lot of difference between wastes and waste, there was an erroneous association between ‘wasteland’ and ‘waste’. For the king, wastes were land that was wasted or useless, since it was not a source of revenue. Though it was not land that was wasted for the people, who did a lot of hunting there and used it for a variety of purposes, in the dominant discourse (which includes the law), the perspective of the commoner has seldom found space or resonance. This wasteland is then alienated to the private industry—i.e. made into property—so that it can be taxed and made ‘productive’. However, production for the manor is very different from production for the community. The dominant usage in modern languages is steeped in property. It is property—whether industrial or capital— that is taken as the normative. In law, defence of property is normative. The word ‘development’ in modern usage implicitly refers to industrial development. In more traditional languages, development always means human development—of the individual and the community. In English however, human development must be specified. Similar usage is seen in terms such as ‘growth’, ‘profit’, ‘structural adjustment’ and ‘reforms’. While The Reformation was to de–institutionalise the church and knowledge, the present day ‘reforms’ are to make polity and society itself more market centric. Therefore these would more accurately be termed deform and deformation from a social and human centric perspective. The consequence of the industrial framework is that industrial intervention is a prerequisite for a life pattern to be recognised, value to be assigned and to disregard the active commons. Language is so influenced by the industrial paradigm that nature is considered empty until mechanical procedures are applied to it. Value comes only from such addition, and soon value is mistaken for price. Since the tools are to measure industrial production, all else is termed empty. However, the tools developed by industrial society measured only the health of the enclosures, the corporations, to the detriment of the larger good. Growth was seen to be good, divorced from its effects on society at large, to the verge of being growth for growth sake. Terms such as ‘jobless growth’ were invented and used, not even recognising the irony, that the purposeless growth described therein closest resembles cancer in the real world. Where there is no industrial intervention, it was considered terra nullius. Earlier, ‘wastes’, though an anthropocentric definition, were not considered empty and certainly not a vacuum. The ‘informal economy’, though the largest in ‘less developed economies’, has no place in the GDP just because it is not measured. Air is considered empty and lifeless, so smoke and other pollutants can be let into it, no matter the bees and pollination The living commons: A historical understanding; page [3] Anita Cheria and Edwin; office@openspace.org.in
  • 4. are vital for forests and agriculture, apart from the insignificant detail of humans needing fresh air to breathe. The indiscriminate use of air and electromagnetic resources have literally pushed out bees and birds, in some cases leading to large scale deaths. The rivers and seas are considered empty so the sewage and toxic waste is poured into them. It extended even to considering ‘the natives’ minds as empty and bereft of culture—terra nullius of the mindscape—if there was no industrial production. As Eric Fromm put it in ‘To Be or To Have,’ Industrial society has contempt for nature—as well as for all things that are not machine made and for all people who are not machine makers. What is not, or cannot, be measured is considered absent. 3.3 Vocabulary of transition: Commons to property The change of usage from commons to common property signals a significant shift in production relations, and the actual relationship between the community and the commons. The commons has always been outside the property framework. When ‘commons’ becomes ‘common property’ it brings the commons firmly within the property framework, enabling the government to enforce the concept of ‘terra nullius’ and ‘eminent domain’. Law, the language of the state, is in the vocabulary of property. The introduction of property introduces ‘trespasser’ and the related term ‘criminal’. Where there is no property, there cannot be trespass. The slip is then rapid: from commons to common property to public property, government property, public private partnership (PPP), and finally private property. PPP itself has different levels: Build Own Transfer (BOT), Build Own Operate Transfer (BOOT) and joint ventures (JV). The state would like to blur the distinction between them and use these terms interchangeably. Their distinct histories, and therefore the legal distinction, must always be kept in mind, because the key difference is in their treatment of ‘property’. This alertness is required due to the central role played by the state in alienating the commons from the commoner. The state would see this creeping acquisition as a right of the state. In a curious reversal, the encroacher state claims that the commoners are encroachers in the commons, and seeks to ‘clear the encroachments’ by evicting the commoners. The commoners, who are indigenous to the commons, cannot be encroachers on the commons. In a curious reversal, encroaching governments around the world routinely label the commoners as encroachers—akin to calling Indians illegal aliens in India—and evicts them from the commons. 3.4 Vocabulary in the urban commons In the urban or ‘built commons’ this gradual transformation is seen in the slow transition from being human centric to machine centric in the progression: path—street—road—highway—expressway. In a path humans are supreme. There is no mechanised transport. Human powered transport such as cycles and carts are rare. In a street too, humans are supreme. Mechanised transport is rare and of the smaller variety. In roads, the primary users—the human beings—are relegated to the sidewalks, and are decidedly second class. This marginalisation turns to exclusion in highways and expressways, where ‘slow moving transport’ is excluded and actively discouraged. They are often fenced off. Community spaces—for hawkers or pleasantries—are possible only on streets, pavements, and footpaths. The notion of roads being for the public—a ‘commons’—has taken a beating in recent years. Footpaths are an essential part of roads, since that is the part of the road that is used by the vendors, pedestrians and those who use public transport. This space is being severely restricted, and sometimes even absent, in cities—both in city centres and in residential neighbourhoods. Instead the roads are being broadened to make space for private vehicles. Though most people travel by public transport, very little space is earmarked for bus lanes, bus stops/bus bays, and passenger shelters at bus stops or footpaths. Cycle tracks are not only absent, use of ‘slow moving’ transportation is prohibited on most flyovers and arterial roads. Footpaths shrink and disappear. This invasion of the street and conquest of the footpath is to have wider roads so that high–rises can be built with larger Floor Space Index (FSI). The vendors have to be removed so that the malls can survive. Non–rivalrous commons suddenly become rivalrous. Language has undergone significant change from the urban commons (‘public’) to urban enclosure: from gardens to parks (off limits to animals including pets), with manicured lawns (off limits to humans too), from markets to malls, from streets to flyovers, and playgrounds to stadiums. Increased crime and aggression, as rest and recreation spaces were commandeered for private use, is a result of this enclosure. New usage such as ‘gated communities’ invading the vocabulary mark the success of enclosure movements and the disconnect of the elite from economic production, cultural vibrancy, and democracy of the city. The living commons: A historical understanding; page [4] Anita Cheria and Edwin; office@openspace.org.in
  • 5. 3.5 The exclusive sacred: Constructing knowledge and the architecture of language The definition of commons and its legal defence rests on the knowledge base. The knowledge base rests on the language employed. The construction of knowledge and the architecture of language is therefore fundamental to the defence of the commons. The physical commons needs the support of knowledge commons such as culture, religion, tradition, law, science, and technology. A fundamental and critical challenge of the knowledge commons is that only some knowledge is acknowledged as knowledge itself, the modern day version of ‘my superstition is scripture but your scriptures are myths’. This enables those of the ‘true knowledge’ to define what is the commons and what is private, who owns what and what is legitimate. The keepers of ‘true knowledge’ can then determine access, control, privilege, and exclusion from the commons. Religion and culture are ways of organising knowledge. They are for enclosing the commons and used as such by the powerful. Though claiming to be ‘universal’—and therefore the ‘commons’ of at least humanity—major religions of the world still are exclusivist not only towards others (calling them pagan, infidel, kafir, Asura, Daeva) but also to those within its fold. The duality enables forced inclusion for resource grab and exclusion for benefits. Though knowledge was shared within the community, the ‘community’ was narrowly defined. It often meant only the male of a sub–sect of a sub–clan. Priesthood is a virtual male monopoly, with different levels of initiation over long periods of trial being a prerequisite for greater access. Knowledge was privatised and jealously guarded by making them ‘sacred’ and only for the ‘chosen’. In extreme cases, even the knowledge of the ‘sacred language’ was prohibited. The poor were not even allowed to learn the language of power—whether Sanskrit, Latin or English. ‘Scriptures’ were kept hidden from the commons, who could not know what they said. Ideological systems such as religion, caste (Varna), race, and patriarchy worked in tandem to reinforce each other and regulate the use of the resources, slowly but inexorably with grinding finality, fencing off the commons. Most often, this ‘regulation’ is to restrict or even prohibit certain sections from using the commons. Slowly, the majority was kept away from ‘the commons’ for various reasons. With ‘might as right’ being the norm, only what could not be enclosed by the dominant remained commons—and the ‘could not’ diminished with every advance of science and technology. 3.6 From property to commons Despite all the talk of ‘commons’ the government sees and can comprehend only ‘grazing land’ or ‘pasture’, and the commoners as ‘encroachers’. The market and the corporate world see the commons as property–in–the– waiting, to be taken over when they have the capacity. Retaking the commons needs a vocabulary of commons—in thought (attitude), speech, policy (intent), law (norms) and programmes (practice). The vocabulary of the commons cannot be a vocabulary of property. To define the commons as common property is to fall into the trap of property relations. Just as a gender just society needs gender inclusive and gender just vocabulary (human, spokesman, spokesperson, spokeswoman), defending the commons needs a vocabulary of commons. 4 Enclosure and re–commoning 4.1 Commons and the state There are many views on the emergence and growth of state. One is that as the family grew the father (or dominant male) became the head of the clan, tribe and finally the king. The other is that the king was the chief of a group of marauders who was paid protection money by the sedentary population to be left alone. The ‘king as father’ kingdoms gave rise to the welfare state, while the ‘king as robber’ gave rise to the colonial, rent–seeking state. This has coloured most discussions on the role of the state, since those coming from different kinds of states would want a larger or smaller role for the state depending on their experience. In India, the state as we know it now, arose from the colonial state, and therefore is extractive. However, history has proved that the state, no matter what its origin, has always turned against its people in the long run, and is a protector of class interests. Though the state can, and does, temporarily align with the interests of the citizens and mouth pro–citizen slogans even longer, the true long–term nature of the state is against communities and commons. 4.2 The feudal era Some collective functions were done by the king for the welfare of the entire kingdom. Good kings used the tax, or protection money, for common services. Depending on your view, these common services were provided by the state because the king was the father and had to take care of his children or because the infrastructure The living commons: A historical understanding; page [5] Anita Cheria and Edwin; office@openspace.org.in
  • 6. would provide more efficient means of extraction from the subjects. Kings built tanks for water storage and roads —the first built commons. As kings expanded their territory, they were assimilative of other cultures. In religion, all gods were fitted into a pantheon, with their relative positions reflecting the strength of their followers on earth. Slowly these were assimilated into a trinity, and then into one all powerful god—the god of the king—who not only owned everything in the universe but was the creator of the universe. The Earth and everything in it belonged to this god. Theoretically, the god was the ‘god of all’, though in practice access to the ‘god of all’ was highly restricted, reflecting the restrictions on the use of ‘commons’. The ‘god of all’ translated into the concept of ‘eminent domain’ which means that the king, or the state, owned everything. The people only had the right to use. The king could extinguish all ‘rights’ at will, including the life of the subjects. The father had similar rights in the family. The idea that the Earth ‘belonged’ to someone—and that we are not ‘of the earth’—was necessary to subjugate the Earth and other beings, including humans. Ownership is always of the ‘lesser’ (woman in patriarchal societies, nature in non–indigenous communities) not of an equal or sacred. First, a god who was outside of creation was created and made ‘the creator’. Then came the identification of the king with the god—either as a direct avatar, or as a descendant. Intellectuals, bards, priests, and other sycophants developed theories of the ‘divine right of kings’ and the ‘scriptures’ that had laws legitimising ownership of the ‘nobility’ and exclusion of the ‘commoners’ (being two sides of a coin). Unfortunately, kings began to believe in the sycophantic paeans, like many who believe their own propaganda and advertisements today. ‘Kings’ whose dominion barely covered a few acres declared themselves lords of the universe, the seven heavens, and the three worlds. The king being a god could, and did, exploit the commons—the people and the resources—since he was ‘outside’ and ‘above’, and therefore ‘greater’, than nature. The commoners were not ‘greater’ than nature, and therefore could not ‘exploit’. This ‘externalising’ is the key distinction between indigenous peoples and all others. For the indigenous people, nature—life—community is a continuum. For all others there is an external god who created and controls nature. Externalising would return as the more pernicious ‘externalities’ of the industrial economy and tools of measurement, which enabled distorted and fundamentally flawed tools to pass off dubious ‘cost benefit analysis’ as science. Exploitation of nature had to await the industrial revolution. The Cartesian formulation created an ideological framework that made it possible for humans to consider themselves as separate from, and superior to, nature. The Cartesian framework resulted in tremendous increase in knowledge, science, and technology, but also made it possible for Homo sapiens to dominate nature on a global scale. Technology made it possible to reach across the spatial ‘buffers’ between communities to dominate and enclose. 4.3 The need for enclosures Enclosures are not always bad and are sometimes even required, such as for security, risk and innovation. The first ‘fencing’ was probably to keep off marauders, the remnants of the hunter gatherers who preyed on the sedentary agriculturists. Enclosure became more common and permanent as the pressure on the land grew and the ‘buffer land’ between communities and individuals diminished, changing non-rivalrous commons into rivalrous commons. Though there was always a territorial component in human habitation, and territories were marked, they followed natural boundaries of hills and streams. There were markers, first bio-markers such as trees and later dressed stones, delimiting territories. Delimiting land was seldom for exclusive use, and non-rivalrous usage was permitted. But markers are very different from privatising land though fencing. Fencing brought in the concept of exclusive use. As the capacity to fence grew, so did the extent of land fenced and the duration. Record keeping and technology enhance fencing infinitely. In agrarian societies, small patches of land could be marked for use by individuals and families but these reverted to the community or the state. These closes were places where there could be risk/innovation within the carrying capacity of the community. Once the innovation was successful, the fruits were shared by the community. There was sufficient space so that the risks were isolated, and the footprint of the communities did not overlap. The capacity of a community to risk is dependent on how secure it is—meaning the state of its buffers, surplus, and how far it is from the survival levels. At survival levels, no community can afford to break away from the tried and tested, i.e. take risk or innovate. Innovation even if it be individual initiative, can only be within the capacity of community to bear the cost of failure without harming security of the community as a whole. Enclosures provide this opportunity and security—as in today’s science laboratories where experiments are conducted in a controlled, isolated space. Only the benefits are released onto the commons. Similar was the case The living commons: A historical understanding; page [6] Anita Cheria and Edwin; office@openspace.org.in
  • 7. with the capitalist invention of the corporation, which was to ring fence the risk so that it did not affect the entire wealth of the investor. 4.4 Commoning knowledge The earliest known attempt to common knowledge in India was by the Buddha (563–486BC), who taught in Pali, the language of the commons. It is no coincidence that both of India’s ancient universities—at Nalanda and Taxila—were Buddhist with about 10,000 students and a teacher student ratio of 1:5. For his trouble, the gatekeepers of knowledge exterminated Buddhism from the land of its origin. A similar attempt to common knowledge had to await the advent of Mohammed in Arabia in the seventh century—over a thousand years—who ensured that Islam was taught in the language of the commons, Arabic. Ironically, it was the adherents of Islam who sacked both the Buddhist universities. Though Christianity was taught in Aramaic, the language of the people, its texts were in Hebrew, Greek and Latin—all languages of the gatekeepers. It reached such a level of exclusion that Europe, where the Roman Catholic church held sway, fell into the ‘age of faith’ or the ‘dark ages’—a term coined by a Roman Catholic Priest. ‘Dark’ in this context meant absence of written records. Literacy levels were close to zero. It took the Reformation, and the insistence of the Protestant Christians on schooling and literacy, for the Roman Catholics to turn their attention to literacy in the Counter Reformation. In the millennial belief system on the return of Christ, Christendom launched an attack to ‘liberate the holy land’ at the time of his second coming. The contact of the Europeans with the Arabs during the crusades (1095– 1291) led to the Renaissance (14 th century) and the Reformation (14 th to 16th centuries)—helped in no small measure by the printing press (1440)—that helped democratisation of knowledge. One of the first books to be printed was the Bible, first in Latin and then in the local languages of the people, again making ‘knowledge’ accessible to the commons (the translators were burnt at the stake). With typical German efficiency, the hitherto restricted–to–the–Roman–Catholic–clergy system of education was thrown open to anyone with an interest in studying. An illiterate child could be taught cutting edge knowledge with industrial precision within five years. A decade of schooling was all it took to churn out ‘bachelors’ and ‘masters’ in various specialities—something that took a lifetime before. The schooling system—which socialises knowledge and social mores—was refined over the years so that an illiterate five year old going into the system would understand Nobel Prize winning concepts in less than ten years. However, the dominant soon struck back, and coopted the ‘new normal’. Even today, with ‘universal education’ the rich (privileged) are taught to command and consume and the middle class to manage and save. The poor, as always, are taught to obey and sacrifice. In a commons framework, we would have a commons school system that encourages cooperation. The absence of such a system shows up in very many different ways. The multi–tier schooling system teaches all children for 15 years that collaboration is bad and greed is good—and then society wonders why adults are so selfish and so corrupt. The unintended consequence of the printing press and increased literacy was that oral traditions were wiped out, de–legitimised, or made ‘less’ in short order especially within the legal system. Only written titles and contracts were recognised. Much of the commons were enclosed as reserve forest and exclusive enclaves with the stroke of a pen. Five centuries on, oral traditions have not recovered from this knockout blow, despite development in audio visual technology. With this explosion of knowledge and scientific enquiry came the Age of Reason and the industrial revolution, which enabled fencing on a global scale. 4.5 Colonialism, corporations, capitalism The imperial overreach of the crusades had a debilitating effect on most European monarchies. The crusade– weakened kings were almost bankrupt. They could not conquer the land required to expand their tax base to support their lifestyle. They could not raise taxes on their war weary subjects. Instead, the subjects wrested concessions from them. The Magna Carta, possibly the first citizens’ charter limiting the duties of the king, was signed in 1215. The commoners realised governance—and the capacity to defend the commons—was intrinsic to the commons and they needed to be present when laws and decisions were made regarding the commons. So the House of Commons was established in the 13th and 14th centuries. The surplus (extraordinary profits) created by the industrial revolution made capital accumulation possible, and the merchant class wealthy enough to build ships and launch to foreign lands—something that only kings could do before. So the kings let some of their citizens go out and conquer other (non–Christian) lands for a part of the profits. These citizens would have the exclusive right to plunder the foreign land and its people for a short period The living commons: A historical understanding; page [7] Anita Cheria and Edwin; office@openspace.org.in
  • 8. (similar to patent and copyright) since the conquest was still in the framework of eminent domain. A ‘Royal Charter’ was granted to the Dutch East India Company (DEIC, 1602–1800), British East India Company (BEIC, 1600–1858), and Massachusetts Bay Company (MBC, 1629–1684). DEIC was granted monopoly for 21 years only. The MBC Charter was ‘forever’ subject to payment of 20% tax but was revoked in 55 years. The 15 year monopoly of BEIC was made indefinite in 1609, but the monopoly was revoked by the East India Company Act 1813 (the Charter Act). BEIC had only about a fifth of the business of DEIC, and yet controlled a substantial part of India. Revocation of the charter of BEIC and MBC brought these lands under the direct rule of the British Crown. The corporation as a legal entity was formed, so that the investors could share profits or loss according to the investment. Initially, these companies were incorporated for a single voyage and disbanded with the sharing of its profits. With increase in surplus, the corporations became more permanent with multiple ships and multiple voyages at any given time. Private armies and navies were raised for the protection of the armadas and trade routes. The corporation limited (fenced) the risk to the money invested, and did not extend liability to the entire assets of the investor. The monarch got a share in the profit, and was not liable for any loss. This corporation was a fairly ‘democratic’ entity. With the development of capitalism came democracy, where one man would have one vote (equal share in governance of a nation) just as in a company it was a share in profit in proportion to investment. It was, in a sense, ‘commoning governance’ in the new lands, just as the commoners fought for, and got, the House of Commons in the British Parliament. In the foreign lands considered ‘empty’, terra nullius, the colonisers literally and figuratively fenced off land for their own use. Technology made it possible to fence ever larger areas at increasing distances. Large parts of Africa and Asia were enclosed as game reserves and restrictions were placed on indigenous use of land. Most of this was accomplished through iniquitous declarations and treaties, enforced by the iron fist. To prevent internecine conflict, areas of influence were agreed upon by European powers drawing straight lines on a map. These artificially separated communities and did not have natural geography as borders, leading to many present conflicts, along with the development of technology. 4.6 Democratising knowledge and governance In the colonies, among themselves, the colonisers could move beyond the social and economic boundaries imposed on them by their own societies and nations with some limited social mobility. They freed themselves from the tyranny of the kings and established the rule of law. The commons were beneficiaries of many of the innovations of the companies, chiefly the transparent rule of law (especially contracts), and set procedures of governance. The State could no longer just seize everything. There had to be a clear procedure. Retrospective changes were not permitted. The law of contracts was used by John Locke (1632–1704) when he argued that the king also had a contract with his subjects, and if he broke the contract he could be deposed. The spread of knowledge meant that everyone could have a copy of the contract, and understand what it was explicitly. The modern written constitutions—the contract between the State and the commons—are a direct result. In keeping with the secularisation of knowledge, these contracts have a scope for amendments, a distinction that sets apart these secular ‘bibles’ of the state from the holy books of faith based ideologies which are supposed to be ‘revealed’ and ‘unchangeable’ though incompatible and irrelevant to contemporary times. They are a commoning of governance, keeping pace with contemporary times. Unfortunately for the colonised, might was right. When the king or the corporation could, they did seize the land and violate the law. In India, the schooling system established by Christian missionaries who piggybacked on the mercantile conquest brought knowledge back to the commoners to a degree not witnessed since Buddhist days. Though the first printed Indian work was released on 6 November 1556, the revolution started with 1793 when the trickle turned into a flood that would churn out 86 dictionaries, 115 grammar books and 45 journals in 73 languages of India (apart from the Bible in each of these languages) in a short span. With the backing of the state and the printing press, they could make available books, and therefore knowledge, at an affordable price to the commoner on a scale hitherto unimaginable. Secularising knowledge by setting up the schooling system—first set up to produce clerks for the colonial administration—provided for a lot of upward mobility. Both Ambedkar and Mahatma Phule acknowledged that the advent of the British was far from an unmitigated disaster for the depressed classes. On the contrary, it was a qualified blessing. The living commons: A historical understanding; page [8] Anita Cheria and Edwin; office@openspace.org.in
  • 9. 4.7 The dance of the dinosaurs A couple of centuries after the charters, the companies themselves fell victim to hubris and imperial overreach, and the natives were in revolt everywhere. These companies had fine–tuned their exploitative mechanisms and it was no longer a light touch revenue extraction. Just as the kings before them, these companies exhausted themselves in conquests and turned to the kings for protection or support. The monarchs who were content with taxes, and had rebuilt their strength in the interregnum, could not allow the lucrative revenue stream to dry up, and so directly stepped in with their armed forces to secure the estates and trading posts of the companies. The colonies were brought directly under the British Crown (Massachusetts in 1686, India in 1858), making for global enclosures as against the enclosures within national boundaries earlier. Internally, the rejuvenated state in the 18 th century reverted to its old policy of maximising revenue extraction by taxing even the sunlight streaming into houses, by linking taxes to the number of windows. Though they opened up the knowledge commons, the colonial system fenced ever larger parts of the countryside. As with most second comings, the second coming of the state met with disaster, after initial ‘success’. Within a hundred years most of the known world was colonised, the rapid explosion of technology making even more fencing possible. The turn of the 20th century saw a race for colonisation and resources on an unprecedented scale. This race to fence off the world saw a deepening exclusion of the colonised people from their own lands in greater degree. It could not but end in conflict which, in 1945, resulted in the creation of a new world order after two debilitating wars by the imperial powers in 20 years. With the imperial powers weakened by the global wars, the locals again asserted themselves and reclaimed the commons. This led to a host of wars of national liberation, and many new nations were formed in the 1940s– 1960s. Unfortunately, the locals took over the colonial state and the fences remained. Though there were attempts at recommoning such as nationalising common resources, the state structure remained the same. The world was fenced off between the Capitalist and Soviet blocs. There were sub–blocs within this, as the US continued with the Monroe Doctrine of hemispheric dominance, or in blunt terms, considering the whole of the Americas as its ‘backyard’ where it alone could have any military role, while projecting its military power in remote corners of the globe. The new nation states enforced various copycat forms of restriction, from actual fencing to increasingly intrusive and restrictive visa regimes. Social movements were at the forefront of the recommoning effort. The Suffragettes in the late 19th century, and the feminist movement since the 1960s, tried to being women into the global commons in governance and all public spaces. The most significant successes were that of the women’s movement, closely followed by the civil rights movements (anti-race in USA, and anti-caste in India). These movements directly challenged the fencing of the commons by patriarchy and race/caste. Women, blacks and Dalits demanded and got the right to vote, study, and enter ‘public’ spaces. The anti-war/peace movements demanded that common resources not be wasted for defending the hegemony of the elites or for their turf wars but be used for common good. Capitalism (which started off by breaking the fences put up by feudalism but had by now become another name for privatisation and fencing) struck back using the International Monetary Fund (IMF) and the World Bank. The newly created states were targeted by, in John Perkins famous phrase, ‘economic hit–men’. Structural adjustment, essentially privatising national resources and buying up the local leaders, was the norm to ensure that iniquitous regimes continued. The Regan—Thatcher revolution in both sides of the Atlantic pummelled the commons and the commoners in the 1980s. Public utilities—including water—were privatised in the UK. There was talk of shrinking the state so that it could be flushed down the toilet. With the collapse of the Soviet Union in 1990, capitalist triumphalism even proclaimed the ‘end of history’. The 1990s saw an even more savage round of privatisation that fenced not only the existing resources but laid claim to any that could possibly be discovered anywhere in the universe. GATT (General Agreement in Trade and Tariffs) was followed by the World Trade Organisation (WTO) with its GATS (General Agreement on Trade and Services), IPR (Intellectual Property Rights), TRIPS (Trade Related Intellectual Property Rights), TRIMS (Trade Related Investment Measures), and GAA (General Agreement on Agriculture). New acronyms GM (Genetically Modified) and BT (Biotechnology) found their way into everyday lexicon. Everything became ‘property’ and whatever possible was even physically enclosed. Agreements under the WTO ensure that the knowledge of the industrial societies is kept private while opening up the traditional knowledge as global commons. The World Economic Forum (WEF), a private club with membership of the world’s thousand leading companies, which started in 1971 increased in power and prestige in the 1990s. Its annual meetings in Davos decided the global economic policy for the year. This private club had The living commons: A historical understanding; page [9] Anita Cheria and Edwin; office@openspace.org.in
  • 10. governments come in only as invitees—a reversal of roles that accurately reflected the changed power relations and the state of the commons. Copyright, initially for 14 years, extended progressively to the life of the author and beyond. It became life of author plus 40, to 50, to 60 years, and now is life of the author plus 100 years. Biotechnology led to the unveiling of the human genome, and consequently the patenting of life. The growing privatisation of knowledge resulted in work on GM crops. These crops were considered so commercially valuable that they had a killer gene inserted into them so that they would not be able to reproduce—the farmer would have to get back to the company for the next year’s seeds. Despite polluting adjacent farms, the scientists and marketers thought of their invention as valuable—so much so that they referred to the bees (responsible for most pollination) as ‘pollen robbers’. The mind had become completely warped. The government was captured by the mercantile barons and cared more about consumers than citizens. Even essentials such as water became a commodity and many believed in market pricing water. ‘User fees’ were proposed. Public utility services were handed over to corporations. Rivers were privatised. Bottled water made its appearance. The tipping point was probably 2003 when, for the first time in history, a majority (52 of 100) of the world’s largest economies were corporations and not nation–states. 5 The commons today 5.1 Recognising the fundamental right to commons Within a decade of Capitalism’s triumphalism, the Labour Party (PT) came to power in southern Brazil—in the triumphalist American ‘backyard’. To celebrate they started the ‘World Social Forum’ which grew to be a world assembly of the commons. The organising principles of the WSF are radically different from other such assemblies—no joint statement, no spokespersons, and multiple locations spanning the globe. Since then, the South and Central American peoples have been at the forefront of the global transition to commons. The pushback ‘recommoning’ was most dramatic in the case of water in the first decade of the 21 st century. By the middle of the decade, water was recommoned in Bolivia. In 2006, the water utility company Suez was removed from La Paz Bolivia. It was forced out of Buenos Aires and Santa Fe, Argentina soon after. Adelaide, Australia took back its water from a private consortium after years of being engulfed in a ‘big pong’ (stench) caused by leaking sewers. In India the secretive plans of the World Bank to force privatisation in New Delhi were stalled in 2005. Water as a right was recognised legally by Uruguay on 31 October 2004. South Africa, Ecuador, Ethiopia and Kenya declared water as a human right in their constitutions. In April 2005 the Belgian Parliament passed a constitutional amendment recognising water as a human right. In August 2006, the Indian Supreme Court ruled that protection of natural lakes and ponds is akin to honouring the right to life—the most fundamental right of all. In September 2006 the French Senate accepted ‘the right to access to clean water’. The Netherlands declared the ‘right to water’ through a constitutional amendment in 2008. In January 2011 the Supreme Court of India ordered the protection of the commons, eviction of encroachers and periodic compliance reports in the case before it on encroachment of the village pond, but which it suo moto enlarged to cover all commons. Interestingly, it made a distinction between the encroachers and the commoners directing that the commoners should not be evicted. Before parting with this case we give directions to all the State Governments in the country that they should prepare schemes for eviction of illegal/unauthorized occupants of Gram Sabha/ Gram Panchayat/ Poramboke/ Shamlat land and these must be restored to the Gram Sabha/ Gram Panchayat for the common use of villagers of the village. [...] Regularization should only be permitted in exceptional cases e.g. where lease has been granted under some Government notification to landless labourers or members of Scheduled Castes/Scheduled Tribes, or where there is already a school, dispensary or other public utility on the land. Para 22, CIVIL APPEAL NO.1132 /2011 @ SLP(C) No.3109/2011 Britain too started the process of restoration of commons with the deeply flawed Commons Registration Act 1965, and the Countryside and Rights of Way Act 2000 which entitled walking on all those commons which previously had no access, subject to certain restrictions. The Open Spaces Society could record and protect many commons, including wetlands, despite opposition from the government and the real estate–builders lobby. Commons appropriated during colonial and imperialist times were returned to indigenous people right across the globe. This got a fillip in 1992—500 years after Columbus landed in the ‘new world’—due to concerted action by alliances of indigenous people at all levels, and a misguided attempt by Europeans to ‘celebrate’ the event that The living commons: A historical understanding; page [10] Anita Cheria and Edwin; office@openspace.org.in
  • 11. still was a raw wound for the Africans and the native Americans. Land and resources were returned to indigenous people from Canada to Norway to Australia and New Zealand, in one of the largest decolonisation moves after the 1950s. Even India enacted Panchayat Raj (Extension to Scheduled Areas) Act (PESA) in 1996, followed by the Scheduled Tribes and Other Traditional Forest Dwellers (Recognition of Forest Rights) Act 2006, popularly called the Forest Rights Act (FRA). New commons, and a new understanding of the commons, are emerging to support the survival of the commoners, quite distinct from the digital commons which occupies the ‘new commons’ space in the commons discourse. The new commons in the Indian context is a result of a series of policy changes that have come up as a response to community struggles for survival and dignity. They are an attempt to recognise and ensure certain basic rights for marginalised communities as well as more responsive state functioning. In India there are, and have been, strong movements to ensure recommoning—that the fences are brought down and the enclosures opened up. The anti-caste movement is one such. The women’s movement and that of the sexual minorities are others. What is new is that they are now being institutionalised with constitutional and legal support. The Right to Information Act, RTI, 2005, (recommoning information) which provides transparency in the use of public resources, the National Rural Employment Guarantee Act (recommoning the benefits of the use of national wealth) and the Right to Education Act 2010 which provides for free and compulsory education to all children aged six to fourteen (recommoning knowledge, tearing down the walls of caste and economic privilege), despite flaws, lay a strong foundation for a new commons-led society. Others, such as the FRA, recognise existing commons and attempt to correct historical injustice by returning land and resources to the communities. In fact, these ‘commons’ were fenced off for so long and so effective was prohibition, that these are ‘new’ commons for the majority of women, Dalits, Adivasi and children. In addition, there are a series of Supreme Court orders that recognise silence and natural and mineral resources —including electromagnetic spectrum—as commons that can be privatised only for public utility, and even so for a limited period. The Right to Food campaign is another ongoing process in the same direction that still needs to find an appropriate language of rights, policy and implementation. The law recognises that fencing is only temporary—hence the time limit for patents and copyrights—and that commons are the norm. In 2012, the Supreme Court of India allowed compulsory licensing of an anti–cancer drug —slashing the price of the drug by 97%! The legal framework for returning the commons to the commoners, and restoring the primacy of the commons in the constitutional framework is well underway. In international law, parts of Antarctica are recognised as global commons. So are most of the oceans but for 12 nautical miles from the coastline as ‘territorial waters’. There is right of passage in the 200 nautical mile exclusive economic zones. All of outer space is considered common to humanity (rather arrogant of the human race—since even the Earth is not exclusively a ‘human’ commons). This is in stark contrast to the earlier wave of discovery when the Royal Charters were exclusively for colonising non-Christian lands. Perhaps this is belated acknowledgement of the futility of the concept of terra nullius. Though there are stray attempts from private actors to fence/lay claim to outer space with the possible emergence of technology that would enable such fencing, as of now the international (human) law recognises it as commons. 5.2 A new knowledge base The International Association for the Study of Commons (IASC) was founded in 1989 as an interdisciplinary knowledge sharing community. Through academically rigorous research, sharing of findings and their biennial conferences, it could convincingly prove, in economic terms, the utility of the commons. Elinor Ostrom, a political scientist, got the Economics Nobel for her effort in 2009. This increased interest on the commons, and moved it from being at the bottom of the academic hierarchy, as interdisciplinary studies normally are. The United Nations Development Programme (UNDP) Senior Economist Mahbub ul Haq developed the Human Development Index and Report in 1990, together with Amartya Sen in contrast to the World Bank that brought out the World Development Report. GINI and other indices to measure inequality and wellbeing were invented. At about the same time, there was an explosion of interest in ‘the rights of mother earth’ and the Bolivarian revolution. The knowledge economy made the fatal flaws in tools of measurement of the industrial era painfully evident. Governments commissioned better measures of development. The ‘mass’ nature of technology and business models, especially the internet and mobile telephony, opened up a lot of space. While a security and privacy threat, paradoxically, this very same medium offers privacy and a level playing field to some of the most excluded sections. Sexual minorities excluded from the physical commons have The living commons: A historical understanding; page [11] Anita Cheria and Edwin; office@openspace.org.in
  • 12. found a haven in the virtual anonymity of cyberspace, though law enforcement and moral police turn the anonymity to their advantage by using fake IDs to out identities. The very anti–thesis of the restrictive IPR regimes is the copyleft movement that has come up with ‘creative commons’ with its own standards and licensing. Even capital needs the creativity of FOSS (Free Open Source Software), leading to the paradox of multi–billion dollar software companies financing the Free Software Foundation, implicitly acknowledging that the corporations (closes) need the creativity of ‘crowd computing’ (commons) and that non–monetary incentives are superior creativity enablers. Wikipedia, built totally with free contributions, is way and above all other encyclopaedia both in terms of absolute volume and the breadth of knowledge and matches them in accuracy despite being ‘open’. 3 It is also the most up–to–date of them all, being online and being constantly updated. While practices of copyright and patenting continue for some kinds of knowledge systems, creative commons licensing and a growing free software movement are now mainstream. The share of generic drugs in health care is growing, giving the disease industry a run for their money. The Wikipedia and its various forms show ample evidence of the benefits, wide acceptance and support for commoning. Creative commons are an acknowledgement that knowledge creation is a social process. Freeing the airwaves, the use of free and open source software (FOSS) and hardware are good beginnings. More universities—including ivy leaguers such as Princeton, Harvard and IGNOU—are putting out their course material and research papers in open access, using the power of the internet, ‘commoning’ even more knowledge without intermediaries or gatekeepers. Some even have free online courses—Udacity (Stanford), edX (Harvard and Massachusetts Institute of Technology, MIT) and Coursera (Stanford, Princeton, University of Pennsylvania, and University of Michigan). Udacity encourages collaborative learning among students, possibly leading to cooperation by students in other spheres too. The Government of India has a policy of open access for all publicly funded research. The open design movement includes even highly technical and specialised spheres from computers to cars—from operating systems (Linux, Android) to hardware. Open discovery in health, brings down research costs immeasurably. 5.3 The new economy There is a global shift from an economy based on scarcity to one of surplus. The global institutions of the state and the market are yet to even know of the shift, let alone understand it. The global systems are designed for appropriation and hoarding rather than distribution and sharing. The consequences are butter mountains and milk lakes in Europe being dumped in the sea while there is famine in Africa. In India it has resulted in large-scale rotting of food in godowns, while about half the children are malnourished. The commoners have responded by the freecycle and share economy, totally bypassing the market and measurement indices. ‘Volunteerism’ has increased tremendously over the years, contributing skills and competencies free of cost to the commons. Economic theory and measurement tools too caught up with reality, understanding that the air is not empty nor an externality that can be the thrash can of the world, anymore than the oceans are. Economists took a hard look at ‘externalities’ and devised better measures for corporations. National and international laws, such as the Basel Convention on Hazardous Waste, seek to price in the entire cost of ownership, including safe disposal, and make the manufacturer liable for the pollution caused by the ‘waste’ even after the end of their product life. In this model, use of the global commons for dumping waste is priced in based on the principle ‘the polluter pays’. In the heydays of capitalism, profits were privatised and the costs including pollution were socialised, ‘externalised’, right up to interstellar space. Contracts concerning precious natural resources were leased out on a cost plus basis—as if the contractor was doing the community a favour rather than exploiting scarce natural resources. Now the standards are different. Different regulatory bodies set the terms and conditions for service provision (quality, pollution levels—no more an ‘externality’—and end user pricing). This is a better balance between private enterprise and public service with a more equitable sharing of risk and reward on the one hand and resources and equity on the other. There are some tentative steps towards ‘green accounting’ and ‘green budgeting’ so that the ‘national balance sheet’ would reflect the use of irreplaceable natural resources and the commons and not treat them as externalities. The economic indicator ‘gross domestic product’ or GDP is supplemented by national green accounts that would 3 Jim Giles, ‘Internet encyclopaedias go head to head’, Nature, vol. 438 no. 531 (15 December 2005), Note 4 Chapter 1 quoted by Tapscott D and Williams A D in Wikinomics. www.nature.com/news/2005/051212/full/438900a.html The living commons: A historical understanding; page [12] Anita Cheria and Edwin; office@openspace.org.in
  • 13. take natural capital use into account. The World Bank has developed the ‘adjusted net savings’ (ANS) which they claim is a macro-level indicator of sustainable development that measures the ‘true rate of savings in an economy, taking into account investment in human capital, depletion of natural resources and damage caused by pollution’. ANS is a ‘national balance sheet’ by adding human capital accumulation and deducting natural resources losses. Though a deeply flawed tool (its environmental impact measure does not even begin to capture the cost of global warming), it is a step in the right direction by recognising the need to eliminate ‘externalities’. Though the green economy is a step forward from a sustainable economy, which was a step forward from the ‘enter-exploit-exit’ economy, it is still within the framework of ‘more of the same’—carbon trading, eco- development—that led to the crisis in the first place. Better tools need to be developed, fully within the commons framework. 5.4 To preserve and to protect: the challenges The commoners in Britain lost their first battle in stopping the enclosures, but found their space in governance through the House of Commons, which now prevails over the House of Lords. This leads us to the first challenge of the commons: The commoners need to be sovereign over their commons and have the capacity and willingness to defend it. If not, then it is not their commons. If the community cannot preserve and protect their commons, they will soon be alienated from it. The concept of independent village republics ‘gram swaraj’—the promise of the Indian independence struggle—is based on this. A corollary is that these communities need to be internally just—inclusive and equitable—with increasing space for self–expression. Communities that do not transform themselves to meet the new aspirations of their constituents will soon find themselves disintegrating, their members drifting away and the commons wasting. The mastery of the vocabulary of commons is often by the most regressive sections that seek to keep the commoners away from the commons—in what is called the ‘elite capture’, of both the vocabulary and the commons. Thus the second challenge to the commons is of building inclusive, equitable communities with equal access, benefits and control, capable of defending the commons. Collectives of the invisible communities—of women, Dalits and Adivasis, the disabled and the other disadvantaged—need to be built up so that they can enter into the commons and into its governance. It means building inclusive and representative institutions of production, governance and distribution in a manner that encourages and embraces diversity, difference and dissent. It is relatively easy in small homogenous communities in a small, exclusive geo–political area over which it exercises sovereignty. It becomes more challenging for complex social systems as we move from the micro level towards a ‘global village’ were ‘the community’ includes the richness of diversity. It is a tall order, but well within human capacity and reach. An important rule is that the commons need commons. Commons need other commons to help sustain it—from the physical to the knowledge to the socio–cultural and legal. None of the commons are standalones. The pastures need the land, air and water to survive. Privatising any would lead to the destruction of the other commons. The idea that ‘commons need commons’ covers not only the physical commons such as land, air and water, but also the built commons. To defend the commons an alliance of communities is necessary. The World Social Forum is one such being constructed at the global level. It is not monolithic and its organising principles are very different from the traditional structures. Several regional and national level bodies exist or are in the process of being created. It is important to note that commons is plural. There is a vast diversity within commons, their use, and regulation. What we inherit is a multi–verse of commons across generations: a gift from the past, to be used for present needs, and preserved for posterity. Alienation is not an option. If the vocabulary—formal or colloquial, written and oral —does not support it, then the vocabulary must be grown to support it rather than restrict human endeavour due to linguistic limitations. The state as an institution of property was, is, and always will be, hostile to the commons. This is true even, or perhaps especially, when it uses the language of commons. As its capacity to enclose increases, it seeks to invade and enclose as much of the commons as possible. It will then build arguments for legitimising such conquest. The doctrine of ‘eminent domain’ is a Damocles sword hanging over the commons, which the state views as its ‘property–to–be–cleared of encroachments’. Any expectation that the state will protect the commons is naïve in the extreme and akin to the fox guarding the chicken coop. The state appropriates the commons, displaces the people, destroys their livelihoods, and then magnanimously returns a few crumbs as charity cloaked in the language of rights, entitlements and security—the ‘right’ to The living commons: A historical understanding; page [13] Anita Cheria and Edwin; office@openspace.org.in
  • 14. education, employment scheme, and food ‘security’. Rather than this dependency creating charity, restoration of the commons to the community, strengthening their sustainability, and enhancing their carrying capacity is the true measure of rights and security. But the state, being an institution of property cannot do so, limited as it is by its inherent characteristics and design as an instrument for the protection and promotion of property. It is for communities to retake the commons, and then refashion them to egalitarian ends. The non–physical and the new commons are important, since the concept of ‘control over the commons’ is fundamentally changed with the development of new commons. There is a need for a clear understanding of the role of power, and power relations, with respect to commons. Forcible commoning—internal colonisation—is a potent and ever present threat, whether by ethnic swamping, by slow strangulation, or through religion and jingoistic nationalism. The institutions of property are the greatest threats to the commons. Control of the state by corporations adds a disturbing new dimension. Addressing state and non–state power is an important factor in protecting the commons. Since the state has claimed the sole right to violence, neither it nor power can be ignored by any serious student or supporter of the commons. The present institutions of the state are to protect property. Therefore, it is not the ‘capture of the state’ or its present institutions that is important. These institutions can only protect property. To nurture the commons, a new kind of institution, social organisation, socialisation and reproduction of knowledge—a different way of life itself—is necessary. The state has used words to drown the voices. This happens when words are lost and divorced from the voices that gave rise to them. One can certainly profit from mastering the words and the vocabulary, but real response and change demands more than that. Since the economic restructuring of 1992, there have been some disastrous efforts to privatise water, rivers and water supply. Large tracts of common land (pasture, mangroves, coast and forest) have been invaded and fenced off literally and figuratively resulting in citizens movements forcing temporary rollbacks. However, far from the media glare, active state intervention to dispossess the commoners and indigenous people proceeds at a fast pace. It cannot be business as usual. Looking to business to evolve solutions, using the same tools by whatever label —Clean Development Mechanism (CDM) or carbon trading—will only dig a deeper hole. This is one problem we cannot spend our way out of. It requires a fundamental restructuring of society itself, going to the normative roots and re–examining our belief systems. Groupthink will not suffice. The responsibility of civil society is to ensure equitable communities are in place to reclaim the commons. All solutions cannot be expected to come only from the communities involved, and the civil society has a role to play in the transition and evolution. Connecting and facilitating greater coordination among the movements for restoration of the commons is a task that civil society is ideally positioned to do. Engaging and influencing the lawmakers, developing the knowledge and skill sets around commons, helping communities build higher quality of life through commons based livelihoods are other areas that civil society could consider. Engagement in governance is anathema to civil society, but here again there are signs of hope. The Green Party and the Pirate Party have the requisite base to get elected into the European Parliament and are present there. 5.5 The commons as an answer Still socialised in the Cartesian and dominance framework, there is a widespread belief that the commons is external and it is often forgotten to include humans within them. But as the construct ‘House of Commons’ shows, it was not always so. We have forgotten the fundamental unity of the commons, that ‘we are the living commons’. Strengthening commons institutions lie at the centre of any political and ecological solution. Traditional institutional mechanisms and practices provide a starting point but a communitarian solution should be developed based on the contemporary situation. New commons are constantly emerging and being recognised. They need to be recognised and promoted with appropriate institutional mechanisms for their management and judicious use. These need to be developed at many levels, in micro level village communities, at the meso– and macro–scale. Change of power relations is the true benchmark of success. Building equitable, inclusive communities ensures that all are a part of the commons and that the commons can actually be accessed by all the commoners. Today we are at the threshold of another major global shift. The conditions of the previous shifts are well in place—the imperial overreach, an information revolution, and an assertion of civil society. Collaboration and commons are the way to the future. It is not even a matter of if or when. The change is already underway. —oO(end of document)Oo— The living commons: A historical understanding; page [14] Anita Cheria and Edwin; office@openspace.org.in