SlideShare a Scribd company logo
1 of 190
Copyright © 2005 by the author(s). Published here under license
by the Resilience Alliance.
Cinner, J. 2005. Socioeconomic factors influencing customary
marine tenure in the Indo-Pacific. Ecology
and Society 10(1): 36. [online] URL:
http://www.ecologyandsociety.org/vol10/iss1/art36/
Research
Socioeconomic factors influencing customary marine tenure in
the Indo-Pacific
Joshua Cinner1
ABSTRACT. For generations communities in the Western
Pacific have employed a range of resource
management techniques (including periodic reef closures, gear
restrictions, entry limitations, and the
protection of spawning aggregations) to limit marine resource
use. Localized control over marine resources,
commonly known as customary marine tenure (CMT), is the
legal and cultural foundation for many of
these practices. Because of their perceived potential to meet
both conservation and community goals, these
traditional resource management techniques are being
revitalized by communities, governments, and NGOs
as an integral part of national and regional marine conservation
plans in the Pacific. However, the viability
of conservation strategies built on a foundation of marine tenure
may be in question, as it remains unclear
whether marine tenure systems will be able to withstand the
profound social and economic changes sweeping
the Pacific region. Numerous studies have suggested that
changes in marine tenure are attributed to social
and economic factors, however, specific relationships between
socioeconomic conditions and marine tenure
are still not well understood. This paper examines the social and
economic characteristics of 21 coastal
communities in Papua New Guinea and Indonesia, and explores
the characteristics of the communities that
employ exclusive marine tenure to answer the following
questions: Which socioeconomic factors are related
to the presence of CMT regimes? How might socioeconomic
factors influence the ability of communities
to employ or maintain CMT regimes? Distance to market,
immigration, dependence on fishing, and conflicts
were found to be related to the presence of highly exclusive
marine tenure systems. Exploring these
relationships will help conservation practitioners better
understand how future social changes may influence
the foundation of conservation and development projects.
Key Words: customary marine tenure; common-property;
socioeconomic; Papua New Guinea; Indonesia.
INTRODUCTION
Contrary to Western society's propensity toward
managing marine resources as open-access
situations, another paradigm of common ocean
governance called Customary Marine Tenure
(CMT) is prevalent in parts of the Pacific. Under
CMT, access to inshore marine resources is
generally controlled by social units including
individuals, families, clans or other kinship-based
institutions, and villages (Carrier 1987, Ward 1997).
These marine tenure institutions can range from
relatively simple communally-owned marine areas
from which outsiders are excluded to the complex
and overlapping system of individual and family
rights to space, species, gear, and even specific
techniques of using gear described by Carrier (1987)
and Cinner et al. (in press a) in the Manus province
of Papua New Guinea (PNG). Although CMT has
been documented throughout the World (Hviding
1996), it has reached the highest level of
development in the Western Pacific (Ruddle and
Akimichi 1984), including Japan (Ruddle 1985),
Melanesia (Malinowski 1935, Hviding 1983, 1996,
Wright 1985, Carrier 1987, Aswani 1999, 2002,
Cooke et al. 2000, Foale and Macintyre 2000,
Hickey and Johannes 2002), Polynesia (Hoffmann
2002), Micronesia (Johannes 1981, Zann 1985),
Indonesia (Polunin 1984, Mantjoro 1996, Ruttan
1998, Harkes and Novaczek 2002), and Australia
(Johannes and MacFarlane 1984). Legal recognition
of marine tenure regimes can vary significantly
1James Cook University
http://www.ecologyandsociety.org/vol10/iss1/art36/
mailto:[email protected]
Ecology and Society 10(1): 36
http://www.ecologyandsociety.org/vol10/iss1/art36/
between countries. For example, in PNG customary
ownership of marine resources is formally
recognized in the constitution (Hyndman 1993).
Alternatively, much of neighboring Indonesia is
open-access. However, in some northern and
eastern regions of Indonesia (i.e., parts of Muluku,
North Sulawesi, and West Papua provinces), de
facto marine tenure systems still govern local access
to marine resources (see Polunin 1984, Mantjoro
1996, Ruttan 1998, Harkes and Novaczek 2002).
In response to the degradation of inshore marine
resources in many Pacific countries, governments
and conservation groups are examining whether and
how CMT regimes can be integrated into the modern
conservation context (Cooke et al. 2000, Hoffmann
2002, Johannes 2002). CMT is particularly
important in the context of resource management
because it can serve as the legal and cultural
foundation for other taboos such as gear
prohibitions and spatial restrictions (Ruddle 1998,
Aswani and Hamilton 2004). Where CMT is
recognized, the highly decentralized authority over
marine resources can also facilitate rapid adaptive
response to changes in ecological or social
conditions because decisions about limiting
resource use can be made without the process of
involving a centralized bureaucracy. Basing
resource conservation initiatives around marine
tenure regimes is particularly attractive to
conservation organizations and donors because
enforcement of specific fishing regulations within
a tenure is generally the responsibility of the
resource owner (Asafu-Adjaye 2000). By
empowering community self-enforcement of
fisheries regulations, CMT may provide a cost-
effective means to reduce the burden on government
intervention, regulation, and enforcement (Johannes
1981, Hviding 1996, Ruddle 1998). This is
particularly important in the economic context of
the Pacific where fisheries departments are typically
understaffed and under-funded (Johannes 1981).
Customary tenure regimes are the foundation of
marine governance in much of the Pacific, but they
must be better understood if they are to be
effectively incorporated in resource management
and development initiatives. In particular, very little
is known about the social and economic frameworks
that allow communities to employ or maintain CMT
regimes. An array of theoretical and empirical
research has shown that common property
governance systems can be affected by
socioeconomic factors such as religious or cultural
homogeneity (Ostrom 1990), market influences
(Hviding 1996, Henrich et al. 2001), transaction
costs of decision-making (Ostrom 1990, Sumalde
2004), dependence on resources (Lise 2000,
Agrawal 2001, Zanetell and Knuth 2004), social
capital (Pretty and Ward 2001, Pretty 2003, Pretty
and Smith 2004), conflicts (Polunin 1984, Adams
et al. 2003) settlement patterns (Aswani 2002,
Aswani and Hamilton 2004), and resource
variability (see Agrawal 2002 for a comprehensive
review of the factors influencing the emergence and
successful functioning of common property
institutions). The studies specific to CMT suggest
that many of these social and economic factors can
influence the nature and function of marine tenure
institutions (Pollnac 1984, Polunin 1984, Baines
1989, Watson 1989, Hviding 1996, Cooke et al.
2000, Foale and Macintyre 2000, Aswani 2002),
although specific relationships between socioeconomic
conditions and CMT are sometimes contradictory
and are still not well understood. For example,
Watson (1989) discusses how changing socioeconomic
conditions can render resource management
strategies ineffective and inappropriate. Alternatively,
Hviding (1996) documents how marine tenure rules
became more exclusive for both commercial and
subsistence activities in the Morovo Lagoon in
response to increased prices of particular shells.
Here I ask the following questions: Which
socioeconomic factors are related to the presence of
CMT regimes? How might these socioeconomic
factors influence the ability of communities to
employ or maintain CMT regimes? To date, most
research examining the social, economic, and
cultural factors influencing CMT has utilized a
relatively small number of cases or examined these
issues over a very limited geographical area. Despite
the important contributions that small n case studies
have made toward understanding CMT regimes, a
fundamental limitation of this approach is that it
does not allow us to discern larger patterns in how
CMT regimes may respond to social and economic
factors over a wider geographical context. In this
paper, I seek to complement the more detailed case
studies on the subject by using a comparative
approach to examine the potential socioeconomic
factors influencing viable CMT institutions in 21
coastal communities in Papua New Guinea and
Indonesia.
http://www.ecologyandsociety.org/vol10/iss1/art36/
Ecology and Society 10(1): 36
http://www.ecologyandsociety.org/vol10/iss1/art36/
METHODS
Data collection
Between October 2001 and January 2003, research
was conducted in 15 villages in Papua New Guinea
(PNG) and six villages in North Sulawesi, Indonesia
(Fig. 1). A number of criteria were used to select
the study sites. Research was conducted as part of
an interdisciplinary Wildlife Conservation Society
project that assessed the effectiveness of coral reef
conservation in the Indo-Pacific (Cinner et al. 2003;
Cinner et al. in press b, McClanahan et al.
unpublished data). Agrawal (2001, 2002) suggests
that purposively selecting sites that have variation
in theoretically significant variables is a defensible
sampling methodology in a common-property
research context. Study sites were purposively
selected to encompass a wide range of social,
economic, demographic, and resource governance
conditions (e.g., varying degrees of remoteness,
marine tenure, market influence, dependence on
marine resources, etc.). However, as a result of the
project's intent to integrate both socioeconomic and
ecological data, site selection was constrained
somewhat by the need to have comparable
ecological parameters at each site (coral reef habitat,
current regimes, exposure, etc.), access to SCUBA
facilities (although live onboard dive boats were
used to access two remote study sites in PNG and
two in Indonesia), and project goals of examining
several specific conservation sites of regional
importance (e.g., Bunaken and Kilu). Based on the
fact that the villages were not randomly selected, a
cautious approach to interpreting the results would
suggest that the conclusions drawn from this study
are not necessarily applicable outside of the study
sites.
Research was conducted over an one to three week
period per village using one to four trained local
assistants to aid in data collection. I used theoretical
and empirical research (e.g., Ostrom 1990, Carrier
and Carrier 1991, Agrawal 2001, Aswani 2002;
Pollnac and Johnson in press) and socioeconomic
assessment methodologies designed for coastal
communities (Pollnac 1998, Bunce et al. 2000,
Pollnac and Crawford 2000) to select indicators that
were expected to be related to marine resource
governance in the Indo-Pacific and that were also
feasible to collect during the limited research time
at each site. These were: population, distance to
markets, the percentage of fish bartered or sold in
the market, the type of settlement pattern,
dependence on marine resources, immigration, the
presence of conflicts over marine resources, and the
exclusivity of marine tenure regimes.
A combination of systematic household surveys (for
example, surveying every second or third
household), semi-structured interviews with key
informants (community leaders and resource users),
recording of oral histories, transect walks (walking
through the community with a local to identify and
verify issues), participant observations, descriptions
of daily and seasonal time-use, women’s focus
groups, and analyses of secondary sources such as
population censuses and fisheries records were all
used to gather information and triangulate results.
A total of 954 household surveys were collected.
Sampling within villages was based on a systematic
sample design, where a sampling fraction of every
ith house (e.g. 2nd, 3rd, 4th) was determined by
dividing the total village population by the sample
size (Henry 1990, de Vaus 1991). Variance from
the systematic sample was assumed to be equal to
the estimated variance based on a simple random
sample (Scheaffer et al. 1996). The number of
surveys per community ranged from 15-84 (Table
1), depending largely on the population of the
village, the number of available research assistants,
and the available time per site (this was influenced
by factors such as weather, the availability and
frequency of transportation to certain sites, and
budget requirements such as the cost of the boat
used to access remote sites).
The head of the household was interviewed. If the
head of the household was not available, the
household was revisited later. If the head of the
household was still not available, another adult from
the household was interviewed. The head of the
household could have been either a male or female.
In instances where it was appropriate, more than one
member of the household was interviewed to obtain
the most accurate information about specific
subjects (for example, if a female headed the house
but her eldest son was more knowledgeable about
the household's fishing activities and practices, then
he would be asked about the proportion of fish catch
bartered or sold).
Household surveys were used to gather the
following indicators: dependence on fishing,
immigration, population of the village, and the
percentage of fish sold in the market. Dependence
http://www.ecologyandsociety.org/vol10/iss1/art36/
Ecology and Society 10(1): 36
http://www.ecologyandsociety.org/vol10/iss1/art36/
Fig. 1. Map of study sites.
on fishing was determined by having respondents
list all the occupations the household engaged in for
food or money. Respondents were then asked to rank
these activities in order of importance. Those who
regularly engaged in fishing estimated the
percentage of their fish catch sold or bartered.
Respondents were asked where they were from and
were considered immigrants if they came from
another village. Population was determined by: (1)
counting the number of houses, (2) determining the
average number of persons per household (adults
and children) from the household surveys, and (3)
multiplying this by the number of houses in the
community. This was thought to be more accurate
than relying on census information because the
census record in one community reported almost
twice as many houses as were actually counted.
Key informants were selected using non-probability
sampling techniques, including convenience
sampling (for example, a respondent may be
approached during resource use activities) or
snowball sampling (where community members
will suggest appropriate respondents) (Henry
1990). Between two and fifteen key informants were
interviewed per village. Key informants also
provided information on how exclusive the marine
tenure was. Based on the key informant interviews
http://www.ecologyandsociety.org/vol10/iss1/art36/
Ecology and Society 10(1): 36
http://www.ecologyandsociety.org/vol10/iss1/art36/
Table 1. Summary of study sites.
Village Exclude
non-own-
ers
Settlement
pattern
Conflicts over
marine res-
ources
Population Distance
to market
(km)
%
immigrants
% of fish
bartered
or sold
% ranked
fishing as
primary occ-
upation
# of
household
surveys
Ahus yes nucleated yes 544 21 3.9 68 77 51
Andra yes nucleated yes 479 31 13.6 75 55 44
Gabagaba yes nucleated yes 1708 58 2.6 66 51 38
Kakarotan yes nucleated yes 730 100 2.0 24 27 48
Madina yes dispersed no 564 70 35.0 13 0 32
Muluk yes nucleated yes 333 69 7.5 44 5 41
Para yes dispersed yes 1513 46 27.0 69 56 59
Airbanua no dispersed no 687 45 32.6 52 12 43
Blongko no nucleated no 1332 32 51.9 44 8 77
Bunaken no dispersed yes 3122 16 20.5 72 37 73
Enuk no nucleated no 272 14 27.3 64 24 33
Fissoa no dispersed no 287 85 14.0 18 0 31
Kapitu no dispersed no 1791 60 57.1 66 18 84
Kilu no dispersed no 584 17 25.0 31 0 40
Kranget no nucleated no 2127 1 29.7 67 35 37
Mongol no nucleated no 493 0 64.3 35 18 28
Nusa Lik no nucleated no 273 1 46.2 69 54 15
Patanga no dispersed no 421 20 26.8 26 0 41
Riwo no dispersed no 1136 7 10.8 56 24 37
Tubuseria no nucleated no 5000 25 12.8 NA 18 61
Wadau no nucleated no 324 66 10.0 38 2 41
NA= not available
and confirmed observations, villages were
classified based on whether they: (1) practiced
highly exclusive marine tenure regimes in which
non-owners had to ask permission to access marine
resources (classified as "strong" or "highly
exclusive" marine tenure), or (2) had less exclusive
or no marine tenure regimes in which non-owners
regularly and openly accessed marine resources
without asking permission (classified as "weak" or
"less exclusive" marine tenure). Situations in which
neighboring villages (non-owners) had been
granted revocable use privileges and regularly
accessed marine resources were also classified as
less exclusive. Although this compartmentalization
http://www.ecologyandsociety.org/vol10/iss1/art36/
Ecology and Society 10(1): 36
http://www.ecologyandsociety.org/vol10/iss1/art36/
of a wide range of marine tenure regimes into
comparable categories have undoubtedly lead to
overly simplistic interpretations of their true
complexities (Hviding 1996, McCay and Jentoft
1998), it is hoped that this will be outweighed by
the ability to examine how marine tenure is related
to different social and economic factors that can be
captured best through a broader-scale comparative
study.
Key informants and secondary sources provided
information on the presence of serious or significant
conflicts over marine resources. I defined conflicts
as intense verbal confrontations, use of violence, or
court cases. Communities that reported conflicts
over the previous 12 months or had court cases
pending were considered to have conflicts. Key
informants also provided information on the nearest
market where marine products were regularly
bought and sold. The distance from the village to
markets were measured on topographic maps and
nautical charts. Communities were grouped into two
types of settlement patterns: dispersed or nucleated.
Dispersed settlements were communities that were
spread out and contained distinct sub-villages that
were geographically separated. For example, the
community of Riwo in Madang, PNG, had sub-
villages on two separate islands and was thus
considered a dispersed settlement. Nucleated
settlements were communities that were relatively
contiguous.
Analyses
The socioeconomic characteristics of communities
that excluded all non-owners from accessing
resources within their tenure were compared to the
characteristics of communities where non-owners
were allowed to access marine resources. Four types
of analyses were performed to discern whether the
presence of highly exclusive marine tenure was
related to socioeconomic factors: the Mann Whitney
U test, Fisher's Exact test, effect size, and statistical
power.
The SPSS 11.01 statistical program was used to
determine statistical significance with the Mann-
Whitney U and Fisher's Exact tests. The Mann-
Whitney U test is a non-parametric alternative to
the T-test, which is used to test whether two samples
are independent (Siegel and Castellan 1988). The
Mann-Whitney U test was used to examine whether
ordinal or interval socioeconomic characteristics of
communities with highly exclusive tenure were
significantly different from communities with low
excludability. For example, I used the Mann
Whitney U test to compare the mean (rank of)
percentage of immigrants in communities with
highly exclusive marine tenure to the mean (rank
of) percentage of immigrants in communities with
weaker marine tenure. The frequency of
dichotomous data (i.e., settlement patterns and the
presence of conflicts) in communities with strong
marine tenure was compared to communities with
weak marine tenure using a Fisher’s Exact test. The
Fisher’s Exact test is a non-parametric analysis used
to discern whether two samples are independent
based on the frequency of observed responses in a
2 x 2 contingency table with small independent
samples (Siegel and Castellan 1988). Liberal p
values were accepted for determining statistical
significance (p<0.1), because this is an exploratory
analysis and, based on the moderate sample size of
21 villages, I did not want to exclude any variables
that might be important (i.e., I thought the
consequences of committing a type I error were
more grave than a type II error). To ensure national-
level differences were not driving any of the
patterns, significant differences between socioeconomic
characteristics for Indonesian and New Guinean
sites were tested for as well.
Effect size is a standardized measure of the strength
of the relationship between independent and
dependent variables (Vaske et al. 2002). The
Hedge's effect size was calculated as the difference
between the mean socioeconomic conditions of the
two groups (e.g., mean distance to market of the
communities that employed exclusive marine
tenure regimes minus the mean distance to market
of the communities that did not) divided by the
pooled standard deviation of both groups (Gliner et
al. 2001). Statistical power is the probability of
finding a statistically significant result when there
is a real effect in the population being studied (i.e.,
rejecting the null hypothesis when a research
hypothesis is true) (Cohen 1988). The power of
these relationships was calculated using Statistica
6.0 statistical program.
http://www.ecologyandsociety.org/vol10/iss1/art36/
Ecology and Society 10(1): 36
http://www.ecologyandsociety.org/vol10/iss1/art36/
RESULTS
Socioeconomic characteristics of communities
The 21 communities varied considerably in the
socioeconomic and governance indicators (Table
1). Communities ranged from small hamlets with
only 272 people to large villages of 5,000 people.
The importance of fishing as a livelihood strategy
varied considerably in the communities examined.
The percentage of households that ranked fishing
as the primary occupation varied from 0-77%, with
a mean of 25%. There was also a considerable range
in the market influence (measured as distance to
market and the percentage of fish bartered or sold)
on the communities. Communities ranged from
0-100 km from markets. The mean distance to the
nearest regular market for marine products for all
sites was 37 km and the median distance was 32 km.
The percentage of fish bartered or sold ranged from
13-72% and had a mean of 50%. The percentage of
immigrants ranged from 2-64%, with a mean and
median of 25%. Twelve of the 21 sites were
nucleated settlements and only seven sites reported
conflicts over marine resources. Seven of the 21
communities regularly excluded non-owners from
accessing marine resources. High excludability
occurred in the Sangihe-Talaud part of North
Sulawesi, Indonesia ( Para and Kakarotan
communities), but not the southern communities on
or near the main island. In New Guinea, high
excludability was reported throughout the country.
Socioeconomic factors influencing marine
tenure
Only the population indicator differed significantly
between the sites in New Guinea and Indonesia. The
mean population for the New Guinean sites (970)
was significantly lower than the mean population
for the Indonesian sites (1530) (U = 17, p<0.05).
This lack of difference between countries for other
indicators suggests that national-level differences
in marine tenure or socioeconomic conditions did
not overly influence the analysis.
Four out of seven variables differed significantly
between villages with highly exclusive marine
tenure and those with less exclusive tenure regimes
(Table 2). The presence of conflicts over marine
resources was correlated to the presence of highly
exclusive marine tenure. The percentage of
immigrants was lower in communities with
exclusive marine tenure, the distance to market was
higher in communities with exclusive marine
tenure, and the percentage of households dependent
on fishing was higher in communities with
exclusive marine tenure (although this relationship
was only significant at the p<0.1 level). The large
effect size of these latter three relationships (d>0.93)
suggests that substantial relationships exists (Vaske
et al. 2002) (Table 2). No statistically significant
differences were found in settlement pattern,
population, or the percentage of fish sold in market
between communities with strong and weak marine
tenure. The effect size of the percentage of fish sold
in markets (d=0.1) was very low, suggesting a
minimal relationship (Vaske et al. 2002). However,
the power of this relationship was also very low
(0.05), so it would be difficult to detect differences.
The effect size of population (d=0.37) was
approaching a typical relationship found in the
social sciences (d=0.5) (Vaske et al. 2002), and the
power of this relationship was low (0.12) so the
effect of population may have been real but not
detectable with the sample size used. Note that effect
sizes and power are not computed for dichotomous
indicators (such as settlement pattern and conflicts).
DISCUSSION
This is one of the first studies to quantitatively
explore relationships between socioeconomic
factors and marine tenure over a large spatial scale
with a moderate sample size. This paper found that
communities with strong marine tenure were further
from markets, had lower migration, but had higher
dependence on fishing and conflicts over marine
resources. This study is an important compliment
to the more localized case studies and helps put such
research into a broader context. For example,
Aswani's comparison of marine tenure in the
Roviana and Vonavona lagoons in the Solomon
Islands provide a model for how socioeconomic and
historical factors can result in three marine tenure
patterns (Aswani 1999, 2002, Aswani and Hamilton
2004). Aswani's interpretations of how historical
processes, socioeconomic factors, and demographic
changes affect marine tenure in two coastal villages
in the Solomon Islands suggest market forces and
other exogenous pressures will not necessarily
transform CMT institutions into open-access
regimes (Aswani 1999, 2002). This study found that
the distance to the market was negatively related to
http://www.ecologyandsociety.org/vol10/iss1/art36/
Ecology and Society 10(1): 36
http://www.ecologyandsociety.org/vol10/iss1/art36/
Table 2. Differences in socioeconomic characteristics of
communities with and without exclusive marine
tenure.
Variable Z score P Standardized
effect size (d)
Power
Distance to marketA -2.24 0.03** 0.97 0.51
ImmigrationA -2.16 0.03** 0.97 0.51
Fishing as primary occupationA -1.69 0.09* 0.93 0.50
ConflictsB NA 0.001*** NA NA
Percentage of fish
sold in marketA
-0.59 0.44 0.1 0.05
PopulationA 0 1 0.37 0.12
Settlement patternB NA 0.32 NA NA
AComputed using Mann Whitney U test.
BComputed using Fisher’s exact test.
*** Indicates a statistically significant relationship at alpha?=
0.001
** Indicates a statistically significant relationship at alpha?=
0.05
* Indicates a statistically significant relationship at alpha?= 0.1
NA= not applicable because the variables were dichotomous.
the exclusivity of marine tenure regimes, but
whether the fishery was market or subsistence-
based (measured in the percentage of fish bartered
or sold) was not significant. This suggests that the
strength of marine tenure institutions may be
undermined by connectivity to larger markets,
perhaps by introducing new ways of providing
credit and generating prestige (Agrawal 2002).
Commercial or market value for marine products,
however, may not necessarily diminish the strength
of tenure institutions.
To date, conclusions about how heterogeneity
influences the development and maintenance of
common property institutions remain inconclusive.
Heterogeneity (which can include the often
interrelated economic, cultural, religious, and
resource use differences in a society) has been
shown to have positive, negative, or minimal effects
on common property management (Ruttan and
Borgerhoff Mulder 1999, Glaesel 2000, Pollnac et
al. 2001, Bardhan and Dayton-Johnson 2002;
Pollnac and Johnson in press). This study found a
lower proportion of immigrants in communities
with highly exclusive marine tenure institutions,
which is consistent with notions of high social
capital being an important component of
maintaining common-property management regimes
(Pretty 2003). Cultural heterogeneity associated
with immigration may act to increase the transaction
costs of developing, maintaining, and enforcing
marine tenure regulations (Aswani and Hamilton
2004). Trust, reciprocal arrangements, and
consistent norms are important components of
social capital (Pretty and Smith 2004) that may be
affected by a high proportion of immigrants.
Likewise, immigrants may not perceive the rules,
processes, and authorities governing marine tenure
to be legitimate, and thus may not comply with
established rules (Sutinen and Kuperan 1999).
The relationship found between high dependence
on marine resources and the exclusivity of marine
tenure regimes is consistent with research on an
array of common pool resources that suggests a
positive relationship may exist between resource
dependence and participation in common property
arrangements (Lise 2000, Agrawal 2002, Zanetell
http://www.ecologyandsociety.org/vol10/iss1/art36/
Ecology and Society 10(1): 36
http://www.ecologyandsociety.org/vol10/iss1/art36/
and Knuth 2004). Communities with high
dependence on marine resources may employ
exclusive marine tenure regimes to increase
livelihood security. For example, the Andra and
Ahus Island study sites in Manus, PNG, are small
infertile islands surrounded by large (>5 km2) reef
lagoons. Islanders have limited access to essential
terrestrial resources (e.g., vegetables and firewood)
and consequently their dependence on marine
resources is very high (Cinner et al. in press a).
These communities claim exclusive rights to marine
resources on the reefs surrounding their islands and
reefs along the coast of the main Manus Island
(Carrier 1987, Carrier and Carrier 1989; Cinner et
al. in press a), preventing mainland communities
from accessing marine resources. These exclusive
marine tenure regimes help to create an economic
monopoly on marine resources among fishing
communities (Malinowski 1935) and help to ensure
that island communities have desirable goods to sell
or trade in local markets (Carrier 1987; Cinner et al.
in press a), thereby improving their livelihood
security.
There are several possible explanations for the
relationship between the presence of conflicts and
exclusive marine tenure regimes. Some researchers
suggest that marine tenure regimes may have
developed in response to conflicts and may serve to
mitigate them (Pollnac 1984, Polunin 1984). On the
other hand, the complexity of use rights associated
with marine tenure institutions can cause them to be
continually challenged (Foale and Macintyre 2000).
In Indonesia, the lack of legal recognition of marine
tenure also seemed to cause conflicts over marine
resources. For example, while researching in Para
Island, North Sulawesi, long-standing tenure rights
were challenged by neighboring communities who
claimed that exclusive tenure rights were not legal
under Indonesia’s constitution and attempted to fish
in Para's fishing grounds. The Para community
responded by brandishing a firearm to chase off
fishers from the other community. Interrelationships
among indicators may also help to explain the
relationship between conflicts and exclusive marine
tenure regimes. For example, communities with
exclusive marine tenure regimes (with high
dependence on marine resources) used confiscation
of fishing equipment, intimidation, and even
violence to enforce their tenure. Communities with
lower dependence on marine resources may find the
additional livelihood security that might be gained
from employing exclusive marine tenure is not
worth engaging the conflicts associated with this
type of territory defense.
Several of the factors expected to be related to the
presence of CMT did not demonstrate significant
relationships, including population and settlement
patterns. In a review of the factors influencing the
sustainability of common property institutions,
Agrawal (2002) notes that debates concerning the
effect of population on common property
institutions are highly polarized. Results from this
study as to the effect of population on the presence
of exclusive marine tenure regimes are
inconclusive. The possibility exists that the sample
size used here was too small to detect differences in
these indicators, particularly considering the effect
size for population was approaching a moderate
effect. More interestingly though, is the possibility
that the populations in the communities studied
were too small to detect any effect. Gabagaba and
Para were two of the five largest communities in my
study (the 4th and 5th largest populations,
respectively), but employed CMT (Table 1). These
communities had populations of fewer than 2,000
and the largest population of any community studied
was 5,000 residents. Harkes and Novaczek (2002)
found that traditional management in Indonesia
(called Sasi) dies out in villages greater than 3,000
people. However, Evans et al. (1997) noted that Sasi
was present in a community larger than 14,000
people. Therefore, based on previous research, the
critical population size at which CMT may cease to
function effectively may not have been reached in
this study (or reached by only the two sites with
populations >3,000). The population levels of many
of the study sites were similar to many rural coastal
areas in the provinces studied (e.g., National
Statistics Office 2002a, b), however, urbanized
areas with high populations were not examined. An
interesting area of further inquiry would be to
examine whether or how communities with tens of
thousands of residents could support highly
exclusive marine tenure regimes. Aswani (2002),
and Aswani and Hamilton (2004) also speculated
that nucleated and dispersed settlement patterns
influenced whether and how communities in the
Solomon Islands could develop and maintain
marine tenure regimes. Although this study was not
able to explore in-depth ethnographic accounts of
settlement histories, no relationship was found
between settlement patterns and the strength of
marine tenure institutions. In the broader context,
this suggests that whether communities are
nucleated or dispersed may be less important than
other socioeconomic factors in maintaining marine
http://www.ecologyandsociety.org/vol10/iss1/art36/
Ecology and Society 10(1): 36
http://www.ecologyandsociety.org/vol10/iss1/art36/
tenure regimes.
One of the initial concerns with this study was that
national or regional factors might overshadow the
village level factors examined. However, this did
not appear to be the case: there were few significant
differences in socioeconomic characteristics
between the two countries and several adjacent or
nearby communities reported different marine
tenure regimes, supporting the notion that marine
tenure can vary in response to village-level factors
and is not only a product of regional sociocultural
influences. For example, Madina and Fissoa were
nearby communities of a common language group,
but Madina had high excludability and Fissoa had
low excludability. Another potential concern was
that intersite variability in the resource might have
been very high, which could conceivably influence
the nature of the marine tenure institutions.
Incorporating the ecological criteria in site selection
provided a reasonable assurance that relatively little
variance existed in the resources within each tenure
(i.e., the tenure areas all contain comparable coral
reefs in similar ecological zones). Furthermore, we
can infer from other analyses of the resources within
these sites (Cinner et al. unpublished data; Cinner
et al. in press-b; Cinner and McClanahan
unpublished data) that many of the commercially
valuable species harvested within the tenure sites
such as trochus, beche de mer, and reef fish have
small home ranges (e.g., on the scale of hectares to
kilometers) (Kramer and Chapman 1999) congruent
to the scale of the tenure areas. Therefore, the
possible variance in resource conditions is expected
to have relatively little influence in the observed
tenure institutions.
Speculation
This study was able to tease out several indicators
that were of more importance than others and
provide qualitative descriptions of how these factors
may be related to the presence of CMT. The
limitations inherent in the non-random design of this
study mean these results apply only to these study
sites and should not be generalized to the wider
region. Keeping in mind the limitations of this
study's methodology, it is important to speculate on
whether and how these regimes will be able to adapt
and respond to changes in socioeconomic
conditions.
Marine tenure systems are dynamic institutions that,
through adaptation to changing scenarios, have
proven relatively robust to population pressures and
aspects of economic and political modernization
(Hviding 1998). However, Asia-Pacific is a region
undergoing profound social, economic, and
demographic changes (UNEP 2002), and there may
be social forces that marine tenure regimes are
unable to adapt to. Results from this study suggest
that socioeconomic changes that will increase
immigration, open new markets, and decrease
dependence on marine resources may influence the
ability of communities to employ or maintain
exclusive marine tenure regimes. Under these
scenarios, conservation and development strategies
that rely on high excludability in a community's
tenure may become challenged at their foundation.
Alternatively, results from this study also suggest
CMT may be somewhat resilient to other
socioeconomic factors such as population growth.
Highly exclusive CMT can operate in communities
with populations of 1,700, but strong CMT is related
to low levels of immigration. This suggests that high
endogenous population growth (i.e., not from
immigration) in smaller communities may not affect
the ability to employ viable marine tenure.
The next research challenge is to address the
applicability of these results to the wider region. A
random selection of villages that could be
considered representative of the region would be
desirable for future studies. Another research
priority is determining what specific aspects of these
variables influence marine tenure. For example,
high immigration may cause confusion over use
rights, disrupt traditional information exchange
mechanisms, and/or introduce new ideas that
challenge traditional practices. A better understanding
of how these factors influence marine tenure
regimes will allow development and conservation
organizations to target capacity building and other
activities to potentially increase the resilience of
Pacific conservation strategies against the forces of
social change.
Responses to this article can be read online at:
http://www.ecologyandsociety.org/vol10/iss1/art36/responses/
Acknowledgments:
I thank the people and leaders of all 21 villages for
http://www.ecologyandsociety.org/vol10/iss1/art36/
http://www.ecologyandsociety.org/vol10/iss1/art36/responses/
Ecology and Society 10(1): 36
http://www.ecologyandsociety.org/vol10/iss1/art36/
allowing me to work in their communities. Thanks
to LIPI, the PNG National Research Council, PNG
Department of Environment and Conservation, and
the PNG National Fisheries Authority. The David
and Lucille Packard Foundation supported this
research through the Wildlife Conservation Society.
Thanks to S. Sutton, R. Arthur, J. Carrier, and three
anonymous reviewers for reviewing this manuscript
and providing extremely helpful and constructive
comments.
LITERATURE CITED
Adams, W., D. Brockington, J. Dyson, and B.
Vira. 2003. Managing tragedies: understanding
conflict over common pool resources. Science
302:1915-1916.
Agrawal, A. 2002. Common resources and
institutional stability in E. Ostrom, T. Dietz, N.
Dolsak, P. Stern, S. Stonich, and E. Weber, editors.
The drama of the commons. National Academies
Press, Washington, D.C., USA.
Agrawal, A. 2001. Common property institutions
and sustainable governance of resources. World
Development 29:1649-1672.
Asafu-Adjaye, J. 2000. Customary marine tenure
systems and sustainable fisheries management in
Papua New Guinea. International Journal of Socio
Economics 27:917-926.
Aswani, S., and R. Hamilton. 2004. Integrating
indigenous ecological knowledge and customary
sea tenure with marine science and social science
for conservation of bumphead parrotfish (Bolbometopon
muricatum) in the Roviana Lagoon, Solomon
Islands. Environmental Conservation 31:69-83.
Aswani, S. 2002. Assessing the effects of changing
demographic and consumption patterns on sea
tenure regimes in the Roviana Lagoon, Solomon
Islands. AMBIO 31:272-284.
Aswani, S. 1999. Common property models of sea
tenure: a case study from the Roviana and Vonavona
Lagoons, New Georgia, Solomon Islands. Human
Ecology 27:417-453.
Baines, G. 1989. Traditional resource management
in the Melanesian South Pacific: a development
dilemma. Pages 54-69 in F. Berkes, editor. Common
property resources: ecology and community-based
sustainable development. Belhaven Press, London,
England.
Bardhan, P., and J. Dayton-Johnson. 2002.
Unequal irrigators in E. Ostrom, T. Dietz, N.
Dolsak, P. Stern, S. Stonich, and E. Weber, editors.
The drama of the commons. National Academies
Press, Washington, D.C., USA.
Bunce, L., P. Townsley, R. S. Pomeroy, and R. B.
Pollnac. 2000. Socioeconomic manual for coral reef
management. Australian Institute of Marine
Science, Townsville, Australia.
Carrier, J. 1987. Marine tenure and conservation
in Papua New Guinea. Pages 143-167 in B. McCay,
and J. Acheson, editors. The Question of the
commons: the culture and ecology of common
resources. The University of Arizona Press, Tucson,
Arizona, USA.
Carrier, J., and A. Carrier. 1991. Structure and
process in a Melanesian society: Ponam's progress
in the twentieth century. Harwood Academic
Publishers, Paris, France.
Carrier, J., and A. Carrier. 1989. Wage, trade, and
exchange in Melanesia: a Manus society in the
modern state. University of California Press,
Berkeley, California, USA.
Cinner, J., J. Ben, and M. Marnane. 2003. How
socioeconomic monitoring can assist marine
reserve management: Kimbe Bay, Papua New
Guinea in C. Wilkinson, and A. Green, editors.
Monitoring coral reef marine protected areas.
Australian Institute for Marine Science, Townsville,
Australia.
Cinner, J., T. H. Clark, M. Marnane, T.
McClanahan, and J. Ben. In press a. Trade, tenure,
and tradition: influence of sociocultural factors on
resource use in Melanesia. Conservation Biology.
Cinner, J., M. Marnane, T. McClanahan, and T.
H. Clark. In press b. Conservation and community
benefits from traditional coral reef management at
Ahus Island, Papua New Guinea. Conservation
Biology.
http://www.ecologyandsociety.org/vol10/iss1/art36/
Ecology and Society 10(1): 36
http://www.ecologyandsociety.org/vol10/iss1/art36/
Cohen. 1988. Statistical Power Analysis for
Behavioral Sciences. Lawrence Erlbaum Associates,
Hillsdale, New Jersey, USA.
Cooke, A. J., N. V. C. Polunin, and K. Moce. 2000.
Comparative assessment of stakeholder management
in traditional Fijian fishing-grounds. Environmental
Conservation 27:291-299.
de Vaus, D. A. 1991. Surveys in social research.
UCL, London, England.
Evans, S. M., M. E. Gill, A. S. W. Retraubun, J.
Abrahamz, and J. Dangeubun. 1997. Traditional
management practices and the conservation of the
gastropod (Trochus nilitocus) and fish stocks in the
Maluku Province (Eastern Indonesia). Fisheries
Research 31:83-91.
Foale, S., and M. Macintyre. 2000. Dynamic and
flexible aspects of land and marine tenure at West
Nggela: implications for marine resource
management. Oceania 71:30-45.
Glaesel, H. 2000. State and local resistance to the
expansion of two environmentally harmful marine
fishing techniques in Kenya. Society and Natural
Resources 13:321-338.
Gliner, J., G. Vaske, and G. Morgan. 2001. Null
Hypothesis significance testing: effect size does
matter. Human Dimensions of Wildlife 6:291-301.
Harkes, I., and I. Novaczek. 2002. Presence,
performance, and institutional resilience of sasi, a
traditional management institution in Central
Maluku, Indonesia. Ocean and Coastal Management
45:237-260.
Henrich, J., R. Boyd, S. Bowles, H. Gintis, C.
Camerer, F. Ernst, and R. McElreath. 2001. In
search of homo economicus: behavioral experiments
in fifteen small-scale societies. American Economic
Review 91:73-78.
Henry, G. T. 1990. Practical sampling. Sage
Publications, Newbury Park, California, USA.
Hickey, F., and Johannes, R. E. 2002. Recent
evolution of village-based marine resource
management in Vanuatu. SPC Traditional
Management Bulletin 14:8-21.
Hoffmann, T. C. 2002. The reimplementation of
the Ra'ui: coral reef management in Rarotonga,
Cook Islands. Coastal Management 30:401-418.
Hviding, E. 1998. Contextual flexibility: present
status and future of customary marine tenure in
Solomon Islands. Ocean and Coastal Management
40:253-269.
Hviding, E. 1996. Guardians of the Marovo
Lagoon: Practice, place, and politics in maritime
Melanesia. University Press of Hawai'i, Honolulu,
Hawaii, USA.
Hviding, E. 1983. Keeping the sea: aspects of
marine tenure in Marovo lagoon, Solomon Islands.
Pages 9-44 in K. Ruddle, and R. E. Johannes,
editors. Traditional marine resource management
in the Pacific Basin: an anthology. UNESCO,
Jakarta, Indonesia.
Hyndman, D. 1993. Sea tenure and the
management of living marine resources in Papua
New Guinea. Pacific Studies 16:99-114.
Johannes, R. E. 2002. The renaissance of
community-based marine resource management in
Oceania. Annual Review of Ecological Systems
33:317-340.
Johannes, R. E. 1981. Words of the lagoon: fishing
and marine lore in the Palau district of Micronesia.
University of California Press, Berkeley,
California, USA.
Johannes, R. E., and J. W. MacFarlane. 1984.
Territorial sea rights in the Torres Strait Islands with
emphasis on Murry Island in K. Ruddle, and T.
Akimichi, editors. Maritime institutions in the
Western Pacific. National Museum of Ethnology,
Osaka, Japan.
Kramer, D. L., and M. R. Chapman. 1999.
Implications of fish home range size and relocation
for marine reserve function. Environmental Biology
of Fishes 55:65-79.
Lise, W. 2000. Factors influencing people's
participation in forest management in India.
Ecological Economics 34:379-392.
Malinowski, B. 1935. Coral gardens and their
magic. George Allen and Unwin, London, England.
http://www.ecologyandsociety.org/vol10/iss1/art36/
Ecology and Society 10(1): 36
http://www.ecologyandsociety.org/vol10/iss1/art36/
Mantjoro, E. 1996. Management of traditional
common fishing grounds: the experience of the Para
community, Indonesia. Coastal Management 24:229-250.
McCay, B., and S. Jentoft. 1998. Market or
community failure: critical perspectives on
common property research. Human Organization
57:21-29.
National Statistics Office. 2002a. Census unit
register: Madang province. National Statistics
Office, Port Moresby.
National Statistics Office. 2002b. Census unit
register: Manus province. National Statistics Office,
Port Moresby.
Ostrom, E. 1990. Governing the commons: the
evolution of institutions for collective action.
Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, United
Kingdom.
Pollnac, R. B. 1998. Rapid assessment of
management parameters for coral reefs. University
of Rhode Island, Coastal Resources Center,
Narragansett, Rhode Island, USA.
Pollnac, R. B. 1984. Investigating territorial use
rights among fishermen. Pages 267-284 in K.
Ruddle, and T. Akimichi, editors. Maritime
Institutions in the Western Pacific. National
Museum of Ethnology, Osaka, Japan.
Pollnac, R. B., and B. Crawford. 2000. Assessing
behavioral aspects of coastal resource use. Coastal
Resources Center, University of Rhode Island,
Narragansett, Rhode Island, USA.
Pollnac, R. B., B. R. Crawford, and M. Gorospe.
2001. Discovering factors that influence the success
of community-based marine protected areas in the
Visayas, Philippines. Ocean and Coastal
Management 44:683-710.
Pollnac, R. B., and J. C. Johnson. In press. Folk
management and conservation of marine resources:
towards a theoretical and methodological
assessment in N. Kishigami, and J. Savelle, editors.
Indigenous use and management of marine
resources. National Museum of Ethnology, Osaka,
Japan.
Polunin, N. V. C. 1984. Do traditional marine
"reserves" conserve? A view of Indonesian and New
Guinean evidence. Pages 267-284 in K. Ruddle, and
T. Akimichi, editors. Maritime institutions in the
Western Pacific. National Museum of Ethnology,
Osaka, Japan.
Pretty, J. 2003. Social capital and the collective
management of resources. Science 302:1912-1914.
Pretty, J., and D. Smith. 2004. Social capital in
biodiversity conservation and management.
Conservation Biology 18:631-638.
Pretty, J., and H. Ward. 2001. Social capital and
the environment. World Development 29:209-227.
Ruddle, K. 1998. The context of policy design for
existing community-based fisheries management in
the Pacific Islands. Ocean and Coastal
Management 40:105-126.
Ruddle, K. 1985. The continuity of traditional
management practices: the case of Japanese coastal
fishing. Pages 159-179 in K. Ruddle, and R. E.
Johannes, editors. The traditional knowledge and
management of coastal systems in Asia and the
Pacific. United Nations Environmental and Cultural
Organization, Jakarta Pusat, Indonesia.
Ruddle, K., and T. Akimichi. 1984. Introduction
in K. Ruddle, and T. Akimichi, editors. Maritime
institutions in the Western Pacific. National
Museum of Ethnology, Osaka, Japan.
Ruttan, L. M. 1998. Closing the commons:
cooperation for gain or restraint? Human Ecology
26:43-66.
Ruttan, L. M., and M. Borgerhoff Mulder. 1999.
Are East African pastoralists truly conservationists?
Current Anthropology 40:621-652.
Scheaffer, R. L., W. I. Mendenhall, and L. Ott.
1996. Elementary survey sampling. Wadsworth,
Belmont, California, USA.
Siegel, S., and N. J. Castellan. 1988.
Nonparametric statistics for the behavioral
sciences. McGraw-Hill, New York, USA.
Sumalde, Z. 2004. Transaction costs of
community-based coastal resource management:
the case of San Miguel Bay, Philippines. Coastal
Management 32:51-60.
http://www.ecologyandsociety.org/vol10/iss1/art36/
Ecology and Society 10(1): 36
http://www.ecologyandsociety.org/vol10/iss1/art36/
Sutinen, J. G., and K. Kuperan. 1999. A socio-
economic theory of regulatory compliance.
International Journal of Socio Economics
26:174-193.
UNEP. 2002. Global environmental outlook 3: past,
present, and future perspectives. Earthscan
Publications Ltd., London, England.
Vaske, G., J. Gliner, and G. Morgan. 2002.
Communicating judgements about practical
significance: effect size, confidence intervals, and
odds ratios. Human Dimensions of Wildlife
7:287-300.
Ward, G. R. 1997. Changing forms of communal
tenure. Page 13 in P. Larmour, editor. The
governance of common property in the Pacific
Region. National Centre for Development Studies,
Australian Nation University, Canberra, Australia.
Watson, D. 1989. The evolution of appropriate
resource-management systems. Pages 54-69 in F.
Berkes, editor. Common property resources:
Ecology and community-based sustainable development.
Belhaven Press, London, England.
Wright, A. 1985. Marine resource use in Papua New
Guinea: can traditional concepts and contemporary
development be integrated? Pages 53-77 in K.
Ruddle, and R. E. Johannes, editors. The traditional
knowledge and management of coastal systems in
Asia and the Pacific. United Nations Educational,
Scientific, and Cultural Organization, Jakarta Pusat,
Indonesia.
Zanetell, B. A., and B. A. Knuth. 2004.
Participation rhetoric or community-based management
reality? Influences on willingness to participate in
a Venezuelan freshwater fishery. World Development
32:793-807.
Zann, L. P. 1985. Traditional management and
conservation of fisheries in Kiribati and Tuvalu
atolls. Pages 53-77 in K. Ruddle, and R. E. Johannes,
editors. The traditional knowledge and management
of coastal systems in Asia and the Pacific. United
Nations Environmental and Cultural Organization,
Jakarta Pusat, Indonesia.
http://www.ecologyandsociety.org/vol10/iss1/art36/TitleAbstrac
tIntroductionMethodsData
collectionAnalysesResultsSocioeconomic characteristics of
communitiesSocioeconomic factors influencing marine
tenureDiscussionSpeculationResponses to this
articleAcknowledgmentsLiterature citedFigure1Table1Table2
THE MANAGEMENT
OF COMMON PROPERTY
RESOURCES:
Finding a Cooperative
Solution
Robert
W
hen will villagers come together to produce goods and ser-
vices that they all need but cannot provide individually? In
what circumstances will those who face a potential "tragedy
of the commons" be able to formulate rules by which the
tragedy is
averted?
Many writers on collective action are inclined to think that the
circumstances are very limited. They argue that people in a
situation
in which all could benefit from cooperation will be unlikely to
coop-
erate without an external agent to enforce agreements.
Likewise,
many theorists on property rights argue that common property
re-
sources will be overexploited as demand rises, so only private
enclo-
sure or state regulation stands a chance of preventing such a
result.1
This article offers a critique of some of the analytical arguments
used
to reach these conclusions and argues that they have been
inappro-
priately applied to certain types of village resources. It then
discusses
how to judge whether villagers will be able to sustain local
rules of
restrained access to common property resources and interprets
the
evidence from a study of forty-one villages in South India.
Clearly there can be no general presumption that collective
action
rather than privatization or state regulation will work: witness
the
frequency of degraded grazing commons, despoiled forests,
overex-
ploited groundwater, and depleted fisheries. But there are many
exam-
ples of villagers collectively managing property for long
periods. Pri-
vatization or state regulation is therefore not always essential.
A third
option—local collective action—needs to be taken seriously.
Because
© 1 9 8 7 The International Bank for Reconstruction and
Development/The World Bank 219
less public money is likely to be needed for local collective
action than
for either privatization or state regulation, it makes financial
sense to
establish local rules where circumstances permit.
Common
Property
and
Common-Pool
Resources
On a continuum of property rights, exclusive possession
(freehold)
is at one end. At the other is no property, as in ocean fisheries
or the
atmosphere. In between lies common property, where the rights
to
exploit a resource are held by people in conjunction with each
other.
These rights may take several forms: they may allow unlimited
exploi-
tation for those within a specified group (as happened in
commercial
fisheries under national jurisdiction) or they may stipulate
limits for
each user (as in most commercial fisheries today or as in
"stinting" of
a grazing commons).
Of course, the same type of resource may be exploited under a
variety of property rights. This article deals with those
resources that
might be called "common-pool" resources—a subset of public
goods,
as that term is used in economics. All public goods have the
property
that many people can use them at once, because exclusion is
difficult.
But some public goods yield infinite benefits, in the sense that
if A
uses more there is not less available for others (lighthouses and
weath-
er forecasts, for example). Common-pool resources, by contrast,
are
public goods with finite, or subtractive, benefits: if A uses
more, less
remains for others. Common-pool resources are therefore
potentially
subject to congestion, depletion, or degradation (Blomquist and
Os-
trom 1985; Randall 1983).
Groundwater is an obvious example of a common-pool resource.
It
can be used jointly, but use is subtractive. So when water is
scarce,
the groundwater table is likely to be depleted. Canal irrigation
water,
unfenced grazing land, and unfenced forest all meet the same
criteria.
These three resources—water, grazing, and trees—are vital to
the
livelihoods of millions of people in developing countries; the
question
of how to prevent their overexploitation as population grows is
im-
portant for development policy.
The prevailing answer runs as follows: when people are in a
situa-
tion where they could mutually benefit if all of them restrained
their
use of a common-pool resource, they will not do so unless an
external
agency enforces a suitable rule. Each individual has an
incentive to
ignore the social costs of his behavior for fear that others will
exploit
the resource before he does. As a result, the rate of aggregate
use
exceeds the physical or biological rate at which the resource
renews
itself (Ostrom 1985b).
This argument has been used to justify far-reaching proposals
for
changing the way that common-pool resources are managed
(Ostrom
1985a; Runge 1986). According to one school, full private
property
220 Research Observer 2, no. 2 (July 1987)
rights over the commons are a necessary condition for avoiding
over-
exploitation (Demsetz 1967; North and Thomas 1977; Johnson
1972;
Picardi and Siefert 1976). According to another, it is essential
to give
an external agency—usually the state—full authority to regulate
the
commons (Carruthers and Stoner 1981; Hardin 1968). For both
schools, the policy issue is simply how to achieve the desired
change
with the least opposition from those involved.
Defining the conditions under which users of common-pool re-
sources may voluntarily restrain their use can be considered as a
subproblem of the theory of collective action, also known as the
theory of public goods. Collective action is action by more than
one
person intended to achieve a common goal or satisfy a common
interest (that is, a goal or interest that cannot be obtained by an
individual alone). Achievement means that a public or
collective good
has been provided. The collective action might be setting and
observ-
ing a rule of restrained access to a common-pool resource, and
the
public good might be the sustainable exploitation that results.
One of the theories that has generated pessimism about the
viability
of collective action is Mancur Olson's "logic of collective
action"
(which might better be called the illogic of collective action, or
the
logic of collective inaction). His core proposition is this:
"unless there
is coercion or some other special device to make individuals act
in
their common interest, rational, self-interested individuals will
not act
to achieve their common or group interests" (Olson 1971,
emphasis
added). In other words, the theorem says that (a) voluntary
collective
action will not produce public goods, and (b) collective action
based
on selective (that is, excludable) penalties or rewards may
produce
public goods. Existing cases of common interest groups are thus
to be
explained by selective punishments or inducements.
My findings question this argument.
Theories
of Collective
Action
The conventional view of Indian villages is that they lack any
real
public realm. A number of men are regarded as "big men," in
some
sense first in the village. But there is no clearly defined social
domain
or institution separate from state authority where activities of a
public
nature are carried out, no center of community management
other
than the lowest levels of the state apparatus itself, and no
machinery
for raising resources for public (village) purposes other than
through
state-sanctioned taxation.
I analyzed forty-one villages in South India (Kurnool district,
An-
dhra Pradesh), thirty-one of which are irrigated from one or
another
of two large canal systems, while the other ten are dry. Despite
the
Indian
Villages
Robert Wade 221
conventional view to the contrary, a significant number of these
vil-
lages do provide public goods and services through local
arrange-
ments that have nothing to do with outside bodies, whether
govern-
ment or voluntary agencies.
The Public Kurnool district is semiarid; rainfall averages 620
millimeters a year
Realm m a u m m o d a l distribution. Population density
averages 105 people a
square kilometer (1971), up from 53 in 1870. Seventy percent of
the cultivated area is under foodcrops; only 12 percent is
irrigated.
Thirty-four percent of villages are supplied with electricity
(1971).
There is one tractor for every one or two irrigated villages, and
many
fewer in rainfed villages (1980). Most variation in real wage
rates is
contained within the range of 1.5 to 4.5 kilograms of foodgrain
a day.
In those villages that have a public realm, it consists of four
main
institutions: a village council (distinct from the statutory
Panchayat,
which is moribund in all the forty-one villages); a village
standing
fund (distinct from local government moneys); a group of
village
guards, employed by the council to protect crops from livestock
and
thieves; and a group of "common irrigators," employed by the
council
to distribute water to the rice fields and to help get more water
to the
village through the government-run canal. The council, and
through it
the field guards and common irrigators, are loosely accountable
to an
annual meeting of all the village's farmers.
The council also organizes the supply of many other public
goods
and services, such as repairing wells, ridding the village of
monkeys,
and making donations for a new primary school or a building
where
sick animals can be treated, and so on. All these services except
water
distribution are financed from the village standing fund, for
which the
council raises money in a variety of ways.
Take K village as an example. Its population is just over 3,000.
The
council has about nine members (the number is fixed for any
one year,
but varies slightly from year to year). It has authority to make
deci-
sions affecting all the village. The village's standing fund
spends about
Rs 10,000 a year (in an economy where a male agricultural
laborer
gets Rs 4 a day outside of seasonal peaks). The standing fund
pays the
salaries of the field guards. Four are employed full-time for
most of
the year, and another two to four are added as the harvest
approach-
es. About twelve common irrigators are employed for up to two
and a
half months, for about 1,200 acres of first-season rice. At
harvest
the common irrigators supplement the field guards in protecting
the
crops.
In the sample of thirty-one canal-irrigated villages, eight have
all
four of the main corporate institutions—council, fund, field
guards,
and common irrigators; eleven have some but not all; and
twelve have
222 Research Observer 2, no. 2 (July 1987)
none. These proportions are not necessarily typical of the whole
area,
since the sample was drawn not randomly but with an eye to
ease of
access and a representative range of water arrangements.
Among the
ten dry villages, eight have field guards; six have a village
council; and
six have a village fund.
The impetus for central (village) control comes primarily from
two
distinct sources of social conflict and production loss.
Trespassing
animals and thieves are one. Unrestrained use of irrigation
water is
the other. These are discussed in turn, using K village as an
example.
K has a population density of 159 people a square kilometer.
With
this density goes a farming system of annual cropping (at least
one
crop on each plot each year) and multiple cropping where
irrigation
permits. Little waste or yearly fallow land is left; the village
has no
common, in the sense of a large area available for common
grazing
for a year or more. But oxen and buffalo are needed for traction,
and
they must be fed. During the growing season they graze close to
the
crops, on the verges or on small areas of fallow, which are
treated as
commons. Because fields are not fenced, the animals must be
tethered
or shepherded. But the incentives for careful shepherding or
tethering
are asymmetrical—I may not be unhappy to see my animals get
fat on
your grain. The rationale of the field guards is to make the
incentives
less asymmetrical. During the medieval and early modern period
in
Europe, the open-field system solved the problem primarily by
regu-
lating the cropping; these Indian villagers solve it mainly by
regulating
the livestock.
If the field guards catch an animal grazing a standing crop, they
take it to the village pound, where it remains until its owner
pays a
fine. If just a few animals are involved, the fine is a flat rate—
Rs 2 per
animal during the day, Rs 4 at night. The rate is set by the
council;
the field guards collect and keep the fine, dividing it equally
among
themselves. If many animals are involved, the council uses its
discre-
tion. The fine may run into hundreds of rupees. The field guards
collect it, keep 25 percent, and hand the rest over to the
standing
fund. (In most villages the owner of the damaged crop is not
compen-
sated.) The field guards do not enforce a stinting. The decision
about
how many animals to own and graze is left to each individual.
After the harvest of most of the rainfed crops in February, large
areas of stubble become available for grazing. (Even in irrigated
vil-
lages, the area under rainfed crops is generally greater than the
irri-
gated area.) Each landowner could reserve his stubble for his
own
animals or those he chose to allow. He could do so by posting
guards
around each field or by fencing. But the cost of either method—
the
cost of privatizing the stubble—is very high; all the more so as
each
The
Management
of Grazing
Robert Wade 223
landowner tends to have his holding divided into several
scattered
plots (McCloskey 1975). So, as in the open-field system of
Europe, the
stubble is put in common; private rights to the product of the
land
extend only to the crop, not to the crop residues.
How, in the "corporate" villages, is this commons managed?
Since
the village's own stock of animals is adjusted to the availability
of
year-round grazing, after the harvest it has some surplus
grazing,
which it could rent out to herdsmen from drier parts of the
district.
The market for grazing and manure is organized in two ways. In
one system, a small group of herders bargains with the council
for
exclusive access to the village's grazing. The bargain states how
many
sheep and goats they will bring, when they will come, how long
they
will stay, and how much they will pay for the franchise. Once
the
bargain is made, those herders have exclusive claim to the
village's
grazing, and others can enter only as some leave. Their flocks
graze
over the stubble by day. By night, when the animals drop most
of
their manure, they are put on the plots of particular landowners,
who
pay them an agreed nightly rate per animal. So the herders as a
group
pay the village a lump sum for access to the commons; and they
individually get back part of what they pay through the sale of
manure.
The second method (used in K, among others) is more complex.
Again, a group of herders obtains exclusive access. But instead
of a
group rent, an auction is held regularly (every four days in K) to
decide who will have each flock on his land at night up to the
next
auction. The auction is arranged by the village council. Half the
winning bid (for each flock) is then paid to the herder, and half
goes
to the village fund. In K, some 9,000 to 13,000 animals
commonly
enter the village for about six weeks, and the village fund gets
about
Rs 5,000 in return.
Such a large number of animals entering the village when some
crops (mainly the irrigated ones) are still standing poses a
serious risk
of loss for those crop owners. The response is to tighten the
regula-
tion of the livestock in two ways. One is to stipulate rules for
both
herder and landowner. These rules are read out at the first
auction of
the year and may be read out again if infringed. They are worth
repeating here because they do not fit easily with the view that
Indian
villagers cannot, so to speak, get their act together (although
they
may seem unremarkable compared with the elaborate by-laws of
open-field villages in medieval England cited in Ault 1973).
For the herder:
• He must take the flock to the designated field by 6:30 p.m.
and keep
it there until 8:00 a.m.
• He must not allow the flock to graze standing crops.
2 2 4 Research Observer 2, no. 2 (July 1987)
• He must deposit with the council half the money paid to him
for
the first "turn" (four nights); if he leaves before completing four
turns (sixteen nights), he forfeits his deposit to the village fund.
(This is to discourage herders from leaving before the farmers
have
had their fields manured and cleared of stubble.)
• He must stay within the village boundary; if the farmer asks
him to
go to a field outside he must refuse.
For the farmer:
• He must keep the flock within the village boundary.
• If he prefers to pay the fund or the herder in kind rather than
cash,
he must make the conversion at the rate (in early 1980) of Rs
1.25
per measure of hybrid sorghum or Rs 1.50 of "local" sorghum.
• To help the herder guard the flock at night, he must provide
two
men for each 2,000 head. Hired guards must be paid Rs 3 a
night,
or the equivalent in grain. (This is to prevent the farmer from
sending nonablebodied men, who could be paid less.)
Such rules are not self-enforcing. Any one farmer would have
an
incentive to cheat, by not providing the stipulated number of
guards
or by bringing the flock to a field outside the village boundary.
So joint regulation is carried further by means of village-
appoint-
ed guards.
To pay the guards, it would be possible for the council to set a
flat
rate—so much per cultivated acre—which each landowner had
to
pay. But such an arrangement would be vulnerable to free
riding: a
farmer could delay payment indefinitely, expecting that others
would
not similarly delay. In most villages this free rider problem is
avoided
by raising the money for the guards' salaries from a collective
source.
The chief source is the money received from the sale of the
grazing
franchise, which is generally enough to pay for a semipermanent
team
of field guards.
The "corporate" irrigated villages tend to have several other
sources of revenue for the standing fund, based mostly on the
sale of
council-sanctioned franchises. In addition to the grazing
franchise, a
franchise to sell liquor is a valuable source of revenue. By law
the
franchise is sold in a government-run auction. However, the
corporate
villages usually send just one person from their village, thus
acquiring
the franchise at the lowest price. They then auction it within the
village
which, with competition, produces a higher price. The
difference be-
tween the two prices goes to the village fund. Or again, one
village in
the sample has an irrigation tank (a small reservoir). Each year
the
council stocks it with fingerlings, and later in the year auctions
the
franchise to catch the fish, the money going to the fund. Some
villages
auction the right to collect a commission on all their grain sales.
Robert Wade 2 2 5
The
Management
of Irrigation
Any irrigation system that experiences water shortages poses an
inherent conflict between farmers upstream and those
downstream.
Those upstream have first access, and their supply is relatively
abun-
dant; how much they take determines how much the
downstreamers
will get. Without some rules about access, continual conflicts
are
likely.
The villages in the sample are irrigated from large, government-
run
canals and grow rice in the first (wet) season. The rice is
transplanted
in late July or early August and harvested in December and
January.
By the end of September the heavy rains have normally stopped,
so
the crop depends on canal water. Common irrigators are then
ap-
pointed to allocate the scarce and fluctuating supply of canal
water
over the village's land and also to procure, by various means,
more
water from the government-run supply (which may include
surrepti-
tiously blocking the outlets of upstream villages).
This arrangement is notable in two respects. First, the common
irrigators do not decide how much land will make a claim to the
irrigation water; that is left to individual farmers (as are
decisions
about how many animals to graze). Second, however, once the
com-
mon irrigators are appointed, they take important decisions out
of the
hands of individual farmers, in the name of a villagewide
authority.
The criterion used by the common irrigators is "adequately wet-
ted." Each field is entitled to be adequately wetted, but it cannot
get
more water until the other fields downstream from that outlet
(most
villages have several outlets) have also been adequately wetted.
This
criterion is quite different from the open access, first-come-
first-served
rule that prevails before the common irrigators are appointed.
The
criterion is also quite different from the approach in northwest
India,
where canal water is always scarce; there during a fixed period
of the
week each field is entitled to draw whatever water is flowing in
the
watercourse, but cannot draw more until the same time the
following
week.
The difference in approach presumably derives from the
difference
between rice (in Andhra Pradesh) and other crops (in the
Northwest).
Rice is more adversely affected than other crops if the water
available
is less than potential evapotranspiration; however, rice does not
suffer
from excessive irrigation. As a result, one farmer's
overgenerous irri-
gation of a rice crop can cause drastic yield reductions for
others.
Therefore, whereas the Northwest's "fixed time per acre"
method is
self-policing—the next farmer in line knows exactly when his
turn
should start—the judgment of adequate wetting cannot be left to
each
irrigator and must be made by people answerable to a
villagewide
authority.
Farmers who steal water—who try to influence how much water
226 Research Observer 2, no. 2 (July 1987)
they get once the common irrigators have been appointed—are
liable
to be fined by the council. During a drought, the fines may be
Rs 20
to 50 each time, but the main penalty is the stigma of being
dressed-
down in front of the council.
The common irrigators are paid at harvest time, not from the
village fund but by means of a levy—so much per irrigated
acre—on
each irrigator. The rate is set by the council. Is this not
vulnerable to
free riding? The short answer is no, because the levy is in kind
rather
than cash and is made at the harvest—the one time of the year
when
every farmer has no excuse to delay payment in kind. More
impor-
tant, common irrigators who are not paid one year can damage
the
nonpayer the next year. The withdrawal of common irrigator
services
from one individual's land has graver implications than does the
withdrawal of field-guarding services.
This article has so far discussed how things are done in the
corpo-
rate villages, those with all or most of the four corporate
institutions.
Although most of the detailed information comes from K
village, the
organization of the four key institutions varies little from
village to
village, even though they were not imposed from above.
Many villages, however, have no corporate organization: no
village
council, no standing fund, no common irrigators, and no
village-
appointed guards (though private landowners may hire their
own,
sometimes forming small groups to do so). In these villages the
rule of
open access to canal water applies, although informal turn-
sharing
may develop along some watercourses. And uncoordinated
groups of
herders may enter a village's land at will, or with the permission
of
the headman, and will negotiate with individual farmers about
where
they fold their flocks at night.
Why the difference between the corporate and uncorporate
villages?
The first point is that the corporate irrigated villages are located
toward the tail-end of an irrigation distributary (roughly, the
bottom
one-third of its length; typical distributaries are ten miles long).
The
second point is that the corporate dry villages tend to be located
in
areas with black, rather than red, soil. The third point is that, in
the
semiarid tropics generally, black soil areas tend to be lower
down a
watershed than red soil areas. So irrigated villages toward the
tail-end
of a distributary also tend to have a higher proportion of black
soils.
Black soils are more water-retentive than red soils, allowing a
wider
range of rainfed crops and a higher yield—and hence a more
abun-
dant and varied supply of stubble. With unrestrained access, too
many
animals might come in, damaging the soil. Moreover, the risks
of crop
loss are higher: with the more varied cropping pattern of black
soils,
large areas of stubble from the early-harvested crops will
become
The Ecological
Basis of
Common
Property
Rules
Robert Wade 227
available when other crops are still standing. This provides the
impe-
tus to arrange for the fields to be guarded, which can be
financed by
the herders' willingness to pay for the better grazing on black
soil.
In theory, the power structure of the village might be such that
collective action was impossible because it was not supported
by a
few key households with land close to the canal. In practice,
however,
holdings are typically scattered in small parcels, partly because
land-
owners want to diversify risk. A family with land close to one
irriga-
tion outlet may have another plot close to the tail-end of a block
fed
from another outlet. This greatly helps the consensus on the
need for
rules and joint regulation.
Areas of rainfed cultivation higher up a distributory have more
red
soil, which dries out sooner after the rains stop. They therefore
have
less stubble, so herders are less interested in grazing there. The
higher
irrigated areas tend to be under rice in both seasons, but sheep
and
goat manure is wanted mainly for other crops. So both the
demand
and supply of animals and grazing is less in the higher
villages—and
canal water there is more plentiful and reliable. It is in villages
lower
down a watershed that the potential for conflict is greatest. The
evidence of my sample suggests that these lower villages are
very
likely to have an organized public domain, with rules on the use
of
water and grazing and the provision of other public goods.
How effective are the rules of restrained access in changing the
way
that resources are used? This question is difficult to answer,
because it
is hard to find a pair of similar villages, one with corporate
institu-
tions, one without. All one can say with confidence is that both
production and equity are greater where rules and institutions
apply
than they would have been had the same villages been
unorganized.
Where individual benefits from joint action are high, joint
action is
likely to be forthcoming.
This is not to say that the temptation for self-interested
individuals
to go for immediate gain is minor. The need to respond to the
free
rider problem affects a village's organization. The typical
council has
developed formidable arrangements for enforcing the rules,
precisely
to convince each individual that his fellow villagers will
probably
abide by the rules, so that if he too does so he will not be the
sucker
(Runge 1984). These expectations are reinforced by the social
compo-
sition of the council, an elite body with no pretense at
representation.
Councils have increased their authority with the passage of
time: in
all these villages, they have been operating for several decades
at least.
Lessons What of Olson's argument? One of its main weaknesses
is a lack of
for Theory attention to the size and nature of the collective
benefit.1 It concen-
trates instead on the size of the selective benefits and costs,
those that
2 2 8 Research Observer 2, no. 2 (J"'y 1987)
can discriminate between people according to whether or not
they
help to provide the public good. It simply assumes the net
collective
benefit to be high, since free riders must by definition be among
those
who value the public good highly. So the argument is geared to
interpret noncooperation as evidence for the free rider
hypothesis,
rather than for the hypothesis of low collective benefit. In these
Indian
villages, however, cooperation and noncooperation are
explained in
terms of high and low collective benefit, as indicated by
downstream
or upstream location on a water supply channel and by black or
red
soils. The presence or absence of selective punishments has
little
bearing on the variation among villages.
Another qualification to Olson concerns the source of control
and
punishment. Olson's key proposition—that examples of
collective ac-
tion groups can be explained as the response to selective
punishments
or rewards—differs from the more conventional notion that joint
be-
havior is related to the presence of an external enforcer of
agreements.
Olson is not entirely clear on whether the source of selective
punish-
ment or reward is inside the group or outside. But he can be
read to
mean that the penalties must be organized from outside the
group.
This notion is contradicted by my findings and those of many
others. There are many examples where villagers have
established
rules, monitored the conditions of the commons, checked for
cheat-
ing, and assigned punishment.3 There are also, of course, many
more
examples where attempts to do so have failed; in the absence of
state
regulation or private property, the commons has then
degenerated.
But the successful examples of local rules show that regulation
of the
commons does not have to be imposed from outside (McKean
1984;
Ostrom 1986).
Where Olson and other pessimists about collective action are
surely
right is in the need for coercion to back up agreements. Their
empha-
sis on the difficulties of voluntary collective action is a useful
counter
to the simple optimism of those who believe that community
develop-
ment projects, people's participation, water users' associations,
and
the like are mainly a matter of teaching people about their real
common interests or promoting values that are less
individualistic. On
the contrary, rules that make people do what they may not
imme-
diately want to do are a necessary ingredient of managing
common
resources, so that while free riding tendencies may remain, they
need
not destroy the organization.
The voluntariness of collective action, therefore, has to be
consid-
ered as a constitutional issue and as a matter of action.
Constitution-
ally, people can agree on a set of rules of restrained access or
financial
contributions, their incentive to do so being prospective net
collective
benefit. In action, compliance with the rules must also be
mainly
voluntary, not the result of a calculus of evasion and
punishment. But
Robert Wade 2 2 9
the rules must be backed by a system of punishment, which
helps to
assure each individual that if he follows the rules he will not be
cheated, and which at times of crisis can directly deter
violations.4
Lessons
for
Organiza tional
Design
If an outside authority wanted to encourage the establishment of
some cooperative bodies, how would it choose to design them?
One
lesson is that, in the South Indian context at least, villagers are
likely
to follow joint rules and arrangements only to achieve intensely
felt
needs that could not be met by individual action (Johnston and
Clark
1982). These are likely to involve primarily the defense of
production
(avoidance of crop or animal loss), secondarily the enhancement
of
income, and last by a long way, education, nutrition, health, and
civic
consciousness. The opportunities for avoiding losses or
boosting in-
come by collective action will be taken only if the losses or
gains are
large. In my irrigated villages, corporate organization to
manage com-
mon property is found, with barely an exception, only toward
the
tail-ends of distributaries.
The second lesson is that corporate organizations, to be
effective,
should be based on existing structures of authority. In practice,
this
means that the council will be dominated by the local elite,
which is a
disturbing conclusion for democrats and egalitarians. But rules
made
by the majority of villagers would carry little legitimacy in the
eyes of
the powerful. More important, the effectiveness of a council
depends
on its councillors all having a substantial private interest in
seeing
that it works, and that interest is greater the larger a person's
land-
holding (provided holdings are in scattered parcels). Moreover,
the
tendency of the nonelite to cheat can be checked by the
sanctions of
the village's power structure. Without these wider sanctions, the
coun-
cil's formal penalties would probably be ineffectual. This point
tends
to be overlooked in the public choice literature because it
assumes a
context of free and equal individuals.
If the elite runs the council, will it not become another
instrument
of exploitation? That is not so in these Indian villages, which
reflects
the third design lesson: the council is concerned only with
nonpriva-
tizable benefits. It is not involved in supplying inputs other than
water. It is not involved in settling disputes unrelated to
husbandry or
water. It does not try to compensate the owners of animal-
damaged
crops, for that would create conflict about privatizable value. In
K
village, the council once tried to intervene in the allocation of a
privatizable good (rationed sugar): the conflicts over who got it
be-
came so strong that the council almost ceased to function.
The fourth lesson is that a council should take on less vital
func-
tions (well repairing, monkey catching, and so on) only when it
is
very good at the core (income-defending or income-enhancing)
activi-
230 Research Observer 2, no. 2 (July 1987)
ties. Not all those councils that are organized to do the
essentials also
do much less-essential work.
The fifth lesson is to keep the techniques of calculation and
control
simple. Some record keeping and accountability are needed, so
as to
"institutionalize suspicion," in Ronald Dore's phrase (1971). But
the
accountability procedures are straightforward in these Indian
villages.
There is an annual general meeting of all farmers to discuss the
forth-
coming season, ratify the new council, and receive nominations
for
guards. The records on standing fund income and expenditure
are
simple and are read out at the general meeting. Meetings of the
council
are held in the open, and anyone who passes can listen on the
fringes.
One specific lesson is that, where water users' associations are
deliberately fostered, the right unit of organization is usually
the
whole village. Attempts to form a water users' association
around
each canal outlet are likely to be futile if such a group of
farmers does
not already do other things together. The group will simply not
contain enough authority. Yet many programs for irrigation
improve-
ment in India assume that the natural unit of organization is the
outlet or some other hydrologically defined unit.
More generally, what can be said about the conditions on which
successful collective action depends? In the extreme case—
many users,
unclear boundaries of the common, resources, people scattered
over a
large area, rules easy to break—degradation of the commons can
confidently be expected as demand increases, and privatization
or
state regulation may be the only options. The likelihood of
successful
collective action therefore depends on the following:5
• Resources. The smaller and more clearly defined the
boundaries of
the common resources, the greater the chances of success.
• Technology. The higher the costs of exclusion technology
(such as
fencing), the better the chances of success.
• Relation between resources and users
Location: The greater the overlap between the location of the
common-pool resources and the residence of the users, the
greater
the chances of success.
Users' demands: The greater the demands (up to a limit) and the
more vital the resource for survival, the greater the chances of
success.
Users' knowledge: The more users know about sustainable
yields,
the greater the chances of success.
• Characteristics of users
Size: The smaller the number of users, the better the chances of
success. However, there is a minimum number below which the
tasks able to be performed by such a small group cease to be
meaningful.
Robert Vfftule 231
Boundaries: The more clearly defined the boundaries of the
group,
the better the chances of success.
Relative power of subgroups: The more powerful are those who
benefit from retaining the commons and the weaker are those
who
favor enclosing private property, the better the chances of
success.
Existing arrangements for discussion of common problems: The
more developed such arrangements are, the greater the chances
of success.
Extent to which users are bound by mutual obligation: The more
concerned people are about their social reputations, the better
the
chances of success.
• Noticeability. The more noticeable is cheating on agreements,
the
better the chances of success. Noticeability is a function partly
of
how clearly defined are the resource boundaries, how near they
are
to users' residences, and how large is the group of users.
• Relation between users and the state. The less the state can or
wishes to undermine locally based authorities and the less it can
enforce private property rights effectively, the better the
chances of
success.
As the list implies, there can be no presumption that collective
action will generally work—any more than there can be a
presump-
tion that private property or state regulation will generally
work. My
argument is only that (a) the propensity to descend into anarchy
or
destruction is neither as strong nor as general as mainstream
collective
action theory implies and (b) that where circumstances look
promis-
ing for collective action government officials should treat this
option
as seriously as the other two.
The government can help these local systems by providing a
legal
framework and perhaps technical assistance. The legal
framework
should enable village organizations to obtain legally
enforceable re-
cognition of their identity and rights and to call upon the state
as an
enforcer of last resort (Korten, forthcoming). Obvious though it
may
sound, few governments in Asia have given much attention to
this
task, at least with respect to rural (as distinct from modern
urban)
organizations. If governments did more, their efforts would
widen the
range of situations in which locally based common property
regimes
could be expected to work.
Abstract When will villagers come together to supply
themselves with goods and services that
they all need but could not provide for themselves individually?
Can locally based
collective action be a viable way to manage common property
resources? Many writers
on collective action and common property are pessimistic about
the ability of people
who face problems with common property resources to organize
sustainable patterns
of use for themselves. Some writers favor privatization of the
commons as the only viable
solution; others, the imposition of state regulation. This article
shows, with reference
2 3 2 Research Observer 2, no. 2 (July 1987)
to Mancur Olson's "logic of collective action," that the
analytical basis for this
pessimism is weak for the village-based use of common
property resources. There can
thus be no general presumption that collective action will fail in
the management of
common property resources, any more than there can be a
general presumption that it
will work. The article suggests that the chances of success
through collective action
depend on the characteristics of the resources, the user group,
and group-state relations.
This article is based on a forthcoming book, Village Republics:
Economic Conditions NotCS
for Collective Action in South India, Cambridge University
Press. I am grateful to Hans
Binswanger, Richard Kimber, Ford Runge, and especially Elinor
Ostrom for discussions
on various points of the argument.
1. For references, see citations later in text.
2. It is not that Olson says or implies that the size of the
collective net benefit is
irrelevant; he simply does not give it much attention.
3. For example, McKean (1984) on Japan; Gilles and Jamtgaard
(1981) on Peru;
Campbell and Godoy (1985) on the Andes; Hitchcock (1980),
Peters (1983), and
Thomsen (1980) on Africa; and Netting (1978) on Switzerland.
See also Runge (1987)
and Ostrom (1985b).
4. This argument is in line with some of the early writings in
public choice theory,
notably Buchanan and Tullock (1962) and Ostrom (1968). Later
work in the public
choice tradition has tended to focus too much on the issue of
financial contributions.
I have not discussed here the issue of group size. Olson's
celebrated theorem, stated
without qualification early in his book, is later restricted to
large groups in a taxonomy
of small, intermediate, and large. He says little about how to
distinguish the three types
of groups in practice, but he might argue that the groups under
discussion here are
intermediate groups and therefore outside the scope of his
argument.
5: See also Ostrom (1985b), the starting point of my own
formulation.
Ault, W. 1973. Open-field Farming in Medieval England: A
Study of Village By-laws.
London: Allen and Unwin.
Blomquist, W., and E. Ostrom. 1985. "Institutional Capacity
and the Resolution of a
Commons Dilemma." Policy Studies Review 5, no. 2: 383-93.
Buchanan, J., and G. Tullock. 1962. The Calculus of Consent.
Ann Arbor: University
of Michigan Press.
Campbell, Bruce, and R. Godoy. 1985. "Common-field
Agriculture: The Andes and
Medieval England Compared." Queens University of Belfast,
Geography Department.
Carruthers, I., and R. Stoner. 1981. Economic Aspects and
Policy Issues in Groundwater
Development. World Bank Staff Working Paper 496.
Washington, D.C.
Demsetz, H. 1967. "Toward a Theory of Property Rights."
American Economic Review
57: 347-59.
Dore, R. 1971. "Modern Cooperatives in Traditional
Communities." In P. Worsley, ed.
Two Blades of Grass. Manchester: Manchester University Press.
Gilles, J. L., and K. Jamtgaard. 1981. "Overgrazing in Pastoral
Areas: The Commons
Reconsidered." Sociologia Ruralis 21: 129-41.
Hardin, G. 1968. "The Tragedy of the Commons." Science 162
(December): 1343-48.
Hitchcock, R. K. 1980. "Tradition, Social Justice, and Land
Reform in Central
Botswana." Journal of African Law 24: 1-34.
Johnson, O. 1972. "Economic Analysis, the Legal Framework
and Land Tenure
Systems." journal of Law and Economics 15: 259-76.
References
Robert Wade 233
Johnston, B., and W. Clark. 1982. "Organization Programs:
Institutional Structures and
Managerial Procedures." In Redesigning Rural Development: A
Strategic Perspective.
Baltimore, Md.: Johns Hopkins University Press.
Korten, F. 1987. "The Policy Framework for Community
Management." In D. Korten,
ed. Community Management: Asian Experiences and
Perspectives. Hartford, Conn.:
Kumarian Press.
McCloskey, D. 1975. "The Persistence of English Common
Fields." In W. Parker and
E. Jones, eds. European Peasants and Their Markets: Essays in
Agrarian Economic
History. Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press.
McKean, M. 1984. "Management of Traditional Common Lands
in Japan." Duke
University, Department of Political Science.
Netting, R. 1978. "Of Men and Meadows: Strategies of Alpine
Land Use." Anthropolog-
ical Quarterly 45, no. 3: 132-44.
North, D., and R. Thomas. 1977. "The First Economic
Revolution." Economic History
Review 30: 229-41.
Olson, M. 1971. The Logic of Collective Action. Cambridge,
Mass.: Harvard University
Press.
Ostrom, E. 1968. "Some Postulated Effects of Learning on
Constitutional Behavior."
Public Choice 5 (Fall): 87-104.
1985a. "Are Successful Efforts to Manage Common-Pool
Resources A Challenge
to the Theories of Garrett Hardin and Mancur Olson?" Working
Paper W85-31.
Indiana University, Workshop in Political Theory and Policy
Analysis.
. . 1985b. "The Rudiments of a Revised Theory of the Origins,
Survival, and
Performance of Institutions for Collective Action." Working
Paper W85-32. Indiana
University, Workshop in Political Theory and Policy Analysis.
. . 1986. "Institutional Arrangements for Resolving the
Commons Dilemma: Some
Contending Approaches." In B. McKay and J. Acheson, eds.
Capturing the Com-
mons. Tucson: University of Arizona Press.
Peters, Pauline. 1983. "Cattlemen, Borehold Syndicates and
Privatization in the Kgatleng
District of Botswana." Ph.D. dissertation, Boston University.
Picardi, A., and W. Siefert. 1976. "A Tragedy of the Commons
in the Sahel." Technology
Review 78: 42-51.
Randall, A.-1.983. "The Problem of Market Failure." Natural
Resources Journal 23, no.
1: 131^*8.
Runge, C. Ford. 1984. "Institutions and the Free Rider: The
Assurance Problem in
Collective Action." Journal of Politics 46: 154-81.
1987. "Common Property and Collective Action in Economic
Development."
World Development. Forthcoming.
Thomsen, James T. 1980. "Peasant Perceptions of Problems and
Possibilities for Local-
Level Management of Trees in Niger and Upper Volta." Paper
presented at the
African Studies Association Meetings, October 15-18.
Wade, Robert. 1985. "Common Property Resource Management
in South Indian
Villages." Agricultural Research Unit Discussion Paper 35.
World Bank, Agriculture
and Rural Development Department, Washington, D.C.
1986. "The Management of Common Property Resources:
Collective Action as
an Alternative to Privatization or State Regulation."
Agricultural Research Unit
Discussion Paper 54. World Bank, Agriculture and Rural
Development Department,
Washington, D.C.
. . 1987. Village Republics: Economic Conditions for Collective
Action in South
Copyright © 2005 by the author(s). Published here under licens.docx
Copyright © 2005 by the author(s). Published here under licens.docx
Copyright © 2005 by the author(s). Published here under licens.docx
Copyright © 2005 by the author(s). Published here under licens.docx
Copyright © 2005 by the author(s). Published here under licens.docx
Copyright © 2005 by the author(s). Published here under licens.docx
Copyright © 2005 by the author(s). Published here under licens.docx
Copyright © 2005 by the author(s). Published here under licens.docx
Copyright © 2005 by the author(s). Published here under licens.docx
Copyright © 2005 by the author(s). Published here under licens.docx
Copyright © 2005 by the author(s). Published here under licens.docx
Copyright © 2005 by the author(s). Published here under licens.docx
Copyright © 2005 by the author(s). Published here under licens.docx
Copyright © 2005 by the author(s). Published here under licens.docx
Copyright © 2005 by the author(s). Published here under licens.docx
Copyright © 2005 by the author(s). Published here under licens.docx
Copyright © 2005 by the author(s). Published here under licens.docx
Copyright © 2005 by the author(s). Published here under licens.docx
Copyright © 2005 by the author(s). Published here under licens.docx
Copyright © 2005 by the author(s). Published here under licens.docx
Copyright © 2005 by the author(s). Published here under licens.docx
Copyright © 2005 by the author(s). Published here under licens.docx
Copyright © 2005 by the author(s). Published here under licens.docx
Copyright © 2005 by the author(s). Published here under licens.docx
Copyright © 2005 by the author(s). Published here under licens.docx
Copyright © 2005 by the author(s). Published here under licens.docx
Copyright © 2005 by the author(s). Published here under licens.docx
Copyright © 2005 by the author(s). Published here under licens.docx
Copyright © 2005 by the author(s). Published here under licens.docx
Copyright © 2005 by the author(s). Published here under licens.docx
Copyright © 2005 by the author(s). Published here under licens.docx
Copyright © 2005 by the author(s). Published here under licens.docx
Copyright © 2005 by the author(s). Published here under licens.docx
Copyright © 2005 by the author(s). Published here under licens.docx
Copyright © 2005 by the author(s). Published here under licens.docx
Copyright © 2005 by the author(s). Published here under licens.docx
Copyright © 2005 by the author(s). Published here under licens.docx
Copyright © 2005 by the author(s). Published here under licens.docx
Copyright © 2005 by the author(s). Published here under licens.docx
Copyright © 2005 by the author(s). Published here under licens.docx
Copyright © 2005 by the author(s). Published here under licens.docx
Copyright © 2005 by the author(s). Published here under licens.docx
Copyright © 2005 by the author(s). Published here under licens.docx
Copyright © 2005 by the author(s). Published here under licens.docx
Copyright © 2005 by the author(s). Published here under licens.docx
Copyright © 2005 by the author(s). Published here under licens.docx
Copyright © 2005 by the author(s). Published here under licens.docx
Copyright © 2005 by the author(s). Published here under licens.docx
Copyright © 2005 by the author(s). Published here under licens.docx
Copyright © 2005 by the author(s). Published here under licens.docx
Copyright © 2005 by the author(s). Published here under licens.docx
Copyright © 2005 by the author(s). Published here under licens.docx
Copyright © 2005 by the author(s). Published here under licens.docx
Copyright © 2005 by the author(s). Published here under licens.docx
Copyright © 2005 by the author(s). Published here under licens.docx
Copyright © 2005 by the author(s). Published here under licens.docx
Copyright © 2005 by the author(s). Published here under licens.docx
Copyright © 2005 by the author(s). Published here under licens.docx
Copyright © 2005 by the author(s). Published here under licens.docx
Copyright © 2005 by the author(s). Published here under licens.docx
Copyright © 2005 by the author(s). Published here under licens.docx
Copyright © 2005 by the author(s). Published here under licens.docx
Copyright © 2005 by the author(s). Published here under licens.docx
Copyright © 2005 by the author(s). Published here under licens.docx
Copyright © 2005 by the author(s). Published here under licens.docx
Copyright © 2005 by the author(s). Published here under licens.docx
Copyright © 2005 by the author(s). Published here under licens.docx
Copyright © 2005 by the author(s). Published here under licens.docx
Copyright © 2005 by the author(s). Published here under licens.docx
Copyright © 2005 by the author(s). Published here under licens.docx
Copyright © 2005 by the author(s). Published here under licens.docx
Copyright © 2005 by the author(s). Published here under licens.docx
Copyright © 2005 by the author(s). Published here under licens.docx
Copyright © 2005 by the author(s). Published here under licens.docx
Copyright © 2005 by the author(s). Published here under licens.docx
Copyright © 2005 by the author(s). Published here under licens.docx
Copyright © 2005 by the author(s). Published here under licens.docx
Copyright © 2005 by the author(s). Published here under licens.docx
Copyright © 2005 by the author(s). Published here under licens.docx
Copyright © 2005 by the author(s). Published here under licens.docx
Copyright © 2005 by the author(s). Published here under licens.docx
Copyright © 2005 by the author(s). Published here under licens.docx
Copyright © 2005 by the author(s). Published here under licens.docx
Copyright © 2005 by the author(s). Published here under licens.docx
Copyright © 2005 by the author(s). Published here under licens.docx
Copyright © 2005 by the author(s). Published here under licens.docx
Copyright © 2005 by the author(s). Published here under licens.docx
Copyright © 2005 by the author(s). Published here under licens.docx
Copyright © 2005 by the author(s). Published here under licens.docx
Copyright © 2005 by the author(s). Published here under licens.docx
Copyright © 2005 by the author(s). Published here under licens.docx
Copyright © 2005 by the author(s). Published here under licens.docx
Copyright © 2005 by the author(s). Published here under licens.docx

More Related Content

Similar to Copyright © 2005 by the author(s). Published here under licens.docx

Socioeconomic considerations in marine resource management
Socioeconomic considerations in marine resource management Socioeconomic considerations in marine resource management
Socioeconomic considerations in marine resource management
Ecotrust
 
STRATEGIES TO MINIMIZE HAZARDS OF CONSTRUCTION ACTIVITIES ON WETLANDS: A CASE...
STRATEGIES TO MINIMIZE HAZARDS OF CONSTRUCTION ACTIVITIES ON WETLANDS: A CASE...STRATEGIES TO MINIMIZE HAZARDS OF CONSTRUCTION ACTIVITIES ON WETLANDS: A CASE...
STRATEGIES TO MINIMIZE HAZARDS OF CONSTRUCTION ACTIVITIES ON WETLANDS: A CASE...
MOSES AMO
 
WCS EBM Facilitator Guide English WEB.PDF
WCS EBM Facilitator Guide English WEB.PDFWCS EBM Facilitator Guide English WEB.PDF
WCS EBM Facilitator Guide English WEB.PDF
Ged Acton
 
Booklet_Lutembe Ecosystems Study
Booklet_Lutembe Ecosystems StudyBooklet_Lutembe Ecosystems Study
Booklet_Lutembe Ecosystems Study
Kwame Kusi-Wiredu
 
Role of lgu's in the management of fisheies
Role of lgu's in the management of fisheiesRole of lgu's in the management of fisheies
Role of lgu's in the management of fisheies
Jeannifer Villanueva
 
Tamimi - socioeconomic dimension of water policy
Tamimi - socioeconomic dimension of water policyTamimi - socioeconomic dimension of water policy
Tamimi - socioeconomic dimension of water policy
WANA forum
 
Tamimi - Socioeconomic Dimension of Water Policy
Tamimi - Socioeconomic Dimension of Water PolicyTamimi - Socioeconomic Dimension of Water Policy
Tamimi - Socioeconomic Dimension of Water Policy
Laura Haddad
 
Critical Review of Managed Annihilation
Critical Review of Managed AnnihilationCritical Review of Managed Annihilation
Critical Review of Managed Annihilation
Caroline Grangier
 

Similar to Copyright © 2005 by the author(s). Published here under licens.docx (20)

Assessing and mapping ecosystem services in a small islands state
Assessing and mapping ecosystem services in a small islands stateAssessing and mapping ecosystem services in a small islands state
Assessing and mapping ecosystem services in a small islands state
 
Socioeconomic considerations in marine resource management
Socioeconomic considerations in marine resource management Socioeconomic considerations in marine resource management
Socioeconomic considerations in marine resource management
 
ECOLOGICAL KNOWLEDGE IN FISHERY MANAGEMENT.pptx
ECOLOGICAL KNOWLEDGE IN FISHERY MANAGEMENT.pptxECOLOGICAL KNOWLEDGE IN FISHERY MANAGEMENT.pptx
ECOLOGICAL KNOWLEDGE IN FISHERY MANAGEMENT.pptx
 
STRATEGIES TO MINIMIZE HAZARDS OF CONSTRUCTION ACTIVITIES ON WETLANDS: A CASE...
STRATEGIES TO MINIMIZE HAZARDS OF CONSTRUCTION ACTIVITIES ON WETLANDS: A CASE...STRATEGIES TO MINIMIZE HAZARDS OF CONSTRUCTION ACTIVITIES ON WETLANDS: A CASE...
STRATEGIES TO MINIMIZE HAZARDS OF CONSTRUCTION ACTIVITIES ON WETLANDS: A CASE...
 
WCS EBM Facilitator Guide English WEB.PDF
WCS EBM Facilitator Guide English WEB.PDFWCS EBM Facilitator Guide English WEB.PDF
WCS EBM Facilitator Guide English WEB.PDF
 
Leveraging Environmental Observation Infrastructure for the Benefit of Society
Leveraging Environmental Observation Infrastructure for the Benefit of SocietyLeveraging Environmental Observation Infrastructure for the Benefit of Society
Leveraging Environmental Observation Infrastructure for the Benefit of Society
 
Grant_Cait_FINAL
Grant_Cait_FINALGrant_Cait_FINAL
Grant_Cait_FINAL
 
Role of government, coastal policy, czm act, of the coastal zone management
Role of government, coastal policy, czm act, of the coastal zone managementRole of government, coastal policy, czm act, of the coastal zone management
Role of government, coastal policy, czm act, of the coastal zone management
 
Indicators of resilience in Socio-Ecological Production Landscapes and Seasca...
Indicators of resilience in Socio-Ecological Production Landscapes and Seasca...Indicators of resilience in Socio-Ecological Production Landscapes and Seasca...
Indicators of resilience in Socio-Ecological Production Landscapes and Seasca...
 
Booklet_Lutembe Ecosystems Study
Booklet_Lutembe Ecosystems StudyBooklet_Lutembe Ecosystems Study
Booklet_Lutembe Ecosystems Study
 
Role of lgu's in the management of fisheies
Role of lgu's in the management of fisheiesRole of lgu's in the management of fisheies
Role of lgu's in the management of fisheies
 
Empowering farmers in conserving soil and water in the sampeyan watershed, si...
Empowering farmers in conserving soil and water in the sampeyan watershed, si...Empowering farmers in conserving soil and water in the sampeyan watershed, si...
Empowering farmers in conserving soil and water in the sampeyan watershed, si...
 
Determinants of Households Willingness to Pay for Conservation of Natural Koo...
Determinants of Households Willingness to Pay for Conservation of Natural Koo...Determinants of Households Willingness to Pay for Conservation of Natural Koo...
Determinants of Households Willingness to Pay for Conservation of Natural Koo...
 
Tamimi - socioeconomic dimension of water policy
Tamimi - socioeconomic dimension of water policyTamimi - socioeconomic dimension of water policy
Tamimi - socioeconomic dimension of water policy
 
Tamimi - Socioeconomic Dimension of Water Policy
Tamimi - Socioeconomic Dimension of Water PolicyTamimi - Socioeconomic Dimension of Water Policy
Tamimi - Socioeconomic Dimension of Water Policy
 
nrs-bim-final
nrs-bim-finalnrs-bim-final
nrs-bim-final
 
Documents; Role of government, coastal policy, CZM act, national marine sanct...
Documents; Role of government, coastal policy, CZM act, national marine sanct...Documents; Role of government, coastal policy, CZM act, national marine sanct...
Documents; Role of government, coastal policy, CZM act, national marine sanct...
 
Bentonicos traducir fin
Bentonicos traducir finBentonicos traducir fin
Bentonicos traducir fin
 
Critical Review of Managed Annihilation
Critical Review of Managed AnnihilationCritical Review of Managed Annihilation
Critical Review of Managed Annihilation
 
MSC Term Paper
MSC Term Paper MSC Term Paper
MSC Term Paper
 

More from bobbywlane695641

Assignment 2 FederalismThe system of federalism was instituted wi.docx
Assignment 2 FederalismThe system of federalism was instituted wi.docxAssignment 2 FederalismThe system of federalism was instituted wi.docx
Assignment 2 FederalismThe system of federalism was instituted wi.docx
bobbywlane695641
 
Assignment 2 FederalismThe system of federalism was instituted .docx
Assignment 2 FederalismThe system of federalism was instituted .docxAssignment 2 FederalismThe system of federalism was instituted .docx
Assignment 2 FederalismThe system of federalism was instituted .docx
bobbywlane695641
 
Assignment 2 Evidence Based Practice at Good Seed Drop-InAcco.docx
Assignment 2 Evidence Based Practice at Good Seed Drop-InAcco.docxAssignment 2 Evidence Based Practice at Good Seed Drop-InAcco.docx
Assignment 2 Evidence Based Practice at Good Seed Drop-InAcco.docx
bobbywlane695641
 
Assignment 2 Evidence Based PracticeAccording to the Council .docx
Assignment 2 Evidence Based PracticeAccording to the Council .docxAssignment 2 Evidence Based PracticeAccording to the Council .docx
Assignment 2 Evidence Based PracticeAccording to the Council .docx
bobbywlane695641
 
Assignment 2 Evidence Based PracticeAccording to the Council on.docx
Assignment 2 Evidence Based PracticeAccording to the Council on.docxAssignment 2 Evidence Based PracticeAccording to the Council on.docx
Assignment 2 Evidence Based PracticeAccording to the Council on.docx
bobbywlane695641
 
Assignment 2 Examining DifferencesIn this module, we examined cri.docx
Assignment 2 Examining DifferencesIn this module, we examined cri.docxAssignment 2 Examining DifferencesIn this module, we examined cri.docx
Assignment 2 Examining DifferencesIn this module, we examined cri.docx
bobbywlane695641
 
Assignment 2 Ethical Issues and Foreign InvestmentsBy Friday, A.docx
Assignment 2 Ethical Issues and Foreign InvestmentsBy Friday, A.docxAssignment 2 Ethical Issues and Foreign InvestmentsBy Friday, A.docx
Assignment 2 Ethical Issues and Foreign InvestmentsBy Friday, A.docx
bobbywlane695641
 
Assignment 2 Ethical (Moral) RelativismIn America, many are comfo.docx
Assignment 2 Ethical (Moral) RelativismIn America, many are comfo.docxAssignment 2 Ethical (Moral) RelativismIn America, many are comfo.docx
Assignment 2 Ethical (Moral) RelativismIn America, many are comfo.docx
bobbywlane695641
 
Assignment 2 Essay Power in Swift and Moliere Both Moliere and S.docx
Assignment 2 Essay Power in Swift and Moliere Both Moliere and S.docxAssignment 2 Essay Power in Swift and Moliere Both Moliere and S.docx
Assignment 2 Essay Power in Swift and Moliere Both Moliere and S.docx
bobbywlane695641
 
Assignment 2 E taxonomy· Information TechnologyInformatio.docx
Assignment 2 E taxonomy· Information TechnologyInformatio.docxAssignment 2 E taxonomy· Information TechnologyInformatio.docx
Assignment 2 E taxonomy· Information TechnologyInformatio.docx
bobbywlane695641
 
Assignment 2 Dropbox AssignmentCurrent Trends and Issues in Manag.docx
Assignment 2 Dropbox AssignmentCurrent Trends and Issues in Manag.docxAssignment 2 Dropbox AssignmentCurrent Trends and Issues in Manag.docx
Assignment 2 Dropbox AssignmentCurrent Trends and Issues in Manag.docx
bobbywlane695641
 
Assignment 2 Discussion—The Impact of CommunicationRemember a tim.docx
Assignment 2 Discussion—The Impact of CommunicationRemember a tim.docxAssignment 2 Discussion—The Impact of CommunicationRemember a tim.docx
Assignment 2 Discussion—The Impact of CommunicationRemember a tim.docx
bobbywlane695641
 
Assignment 2 Discussion—Technology and GlobalizationYour Module.docx
Assignment 2 Discussion—Technology and GlobalizationYour Module.docxAssignment 2 Discussion—Technology and GlobalizationYour Module.docx
Assignment 2 Discussion—Technology and GlobalizationYour Module.docx
bobbywlane695641
 
Assignment 2 Discussion—Munger’s Mental ModelsIn his article A L.docx
Assignment 2 Discussion—Munger’s Mental ModelsIn his article A L.docxAssignment 2 Discussion—Munger’s Mental ModelsIn his article A L.docx
Assignment 2 Discussion—Munger’s Mental ModelsIn his article A L.docx
bobbywlane695641
 

More from bobbywlane695641 (20)

Assignment 2 FederalismThe system of federalism was instituted wi.docx
Assignment 2 FederalismThe system of federalism was instituted wi.docxAssignment 2 FederalismThe system of federalism was instituted wi.docx
Assignment 2 FederalismThe system of federalism was instituted wi.docx
 
Assignment 2 FederalismThe system of federalism was instituted .docx
Assignment 2 FederalismThe system of federalism was instituted .docxAssignment 2 FederalismThe system of federalism was instituted .docx
Assignment 2 FederalismThe system of federalism was instituted .docx
 
Assignment 2 Evidence Based Practice at Good Seed Drop-InAcco.docx
Assignment 2 Evidence Based Practice at Good Seed Drop-InAcco.docxAssignment 2 Evidence Based Practice at Good Seed Drop-InAcco.docx
Assignment 2 Evidence Based Practice at Good Seed Drop-InAcco.docx
 
Assignment 2 Evidence Based PracticeAccording to the Council .docx
Assignment 2 Evidence Based PracticeAccording to the Council .docxAssignment 2 Evidence Based PracticeAccording to the Council .docx
Assignment 2 Evidence Based PracticeAccording to the Council .docx
 
Assignment 2 Evidence Based PracticeAccording to the Council on.docx
Assignment 2 Evidence Based PracticeAccording to the Council on.docxAssignment 2 Evidence Based PracticeAccording to the Council on.docx
Assignment 2 Evidence Based PracticeAccording to the Council on.docx
 
Assignment 2 Examining DifferencesIn this module, we examined cri.docx
Assignment 2 Examining DifferencesIn this module, we examined cri.docxAssignment 2 Examining DifferencesIn this module, we examined cri.docx
Assignment 2 Examining DifferencesIn this module, we examined cri.docx
 
Assignment 2 Ethics and Emerging TechnologiesRead the following.docx
Assignment 2 Ethics and Emerging TechnologiesRead the following.docxAssignment 2 Ethics and Emerging TechnologiesRead the following.docx
Assignment 2 Ethics and Emerging TechnologiesRead the following.docx
 
Assignment 2 Ethical Issues and Foreign InvestmentsBy Friday, A.docx
Assignment 2 Ethical Issues and Foreign InvestmentsBy Friday, A.docxAssignment 2 Ethical Issues and Foreign InvestmentsBy Friday, A.docx
Assignment 2 Ethical Issues and Foreign InvestmentsBy Friday, A.docx
 
Assignment 2 Ethical BehaviorIdentify a case in the news that y.docx
Assignment 2 Ethical BehaviorIdentify a case in the news that y.docxAssignment 2 Ethical BehaviorIdentify a case in the news that y.docx
Assignment 2 Ethical BehaviorIdentify a case in the news that y.docx
 
Assignment 2 Ethical (Moral) RelativismIn America, many are comfo.docx
Assignment 2 Ethical (Moral) RelativismIn America, many are comfo.docxAssignment 2 Ethical (Moral) RelativismIn America, many are comfo.docx
Assignment 2 Ethical (Moral) RelativismIn America, many are comfo.docx
 
Assignment 2 Essay Power in Swift and Moliere Both Moliere and S.docx
Assignment 2 Essay Power in Swift and Moliere Both Moliere and S.docxAssignment 2 Essay Power in Swift and Moliere Both Moliere and S.docx
Assignment 2 Essay Power in Swift and Moliere Both Moliere and S.docx
 
Assignment 2 E taxonomy· Information TechnologyInformatio.docx
Assignment 2 E taxonomy· Information TechnologyInformatio.docxAssignment 2 E taxonomy· Information TechnologyInformatio.docx
Assignment 2 E taxonomy· Information TechnologyInformatio.docx
 
Assignment 2 Dropbox AssignmentCurrent Trends and Issues in Manag.docx
Assignment 2 Dropbox AssignmentCurrent Trends and Issues in Manag.docxAssignment 2 Dropbox AssignmentCurrent Trends and Issues in Manag.docx
Assignment 2 Dropbox AssignmentCurrent Trends and Issues in Manag.docx
 
Assignment 2 Discussion—The Impact of CommunicationRemember a tim.docx
Assignment 2 Discussion—The Impact of CommunicationRemember a tim.docxAssignment 2 Discussion—The Impact of CommunicationRemember a tim.docx
Assignment 2 Discussion—The Impact of CommunicationRemember a tim.docx
 
Assignment 2 Discussion—Technology and GlobalizationYour Module.docx
Assignment 2 Discussion—Technology and GlobalizationYour Module.docxAssignment 2 Discussion—Technology and GlobalizationYour Module.docx
Assignment 2 Discussion—Technology and GlobalizationYour Module.docx
 
Assignment 2 Discussion—Providing GuidanceThe Genesis team has re.docx
Assignment 2 Discussion—Providing GuidanceThe Genesis team has re.docxAssignment 2 Discussion—Providing GuidanceThe Genesis team has re.docx
Assignment 2 Discussion—Providing GuidanceThe Genesis team has re.docx
 
Assignment 2 Discussion—Munger’s Mental ModelsIn his article A L.docx
Assignment 2 Discussion—Munger’s Mental ModelsIn his article A L.docxAssignment 2 Discussion—Munger’s Mental ModelsIn his article A L.docx
Assignment 2 Discussion—Munger’s Mental ModelsIn his article A L.docx
 
Assignment 2 DiscussionDuring the first year or two of its exis.docx
Assignment 2 DiscussionDuring the first year or two of its exis.docxAssignment 2 DiscussionDuring the first year or two of its exis.docx
Assignment 2 DiscussionDuring the first year or two of its exis.docx
 
Assignment 2 Discussion QuestionWorking in teams leads to complex.docx
Assignment 2 Discussion QuestionWorking in teams leads to complex.docxAssignment 2 Discussion QuestionWorking in teams leads to complex.docx
Assignment 2 Discussion QuestionWorking in teams leads to complex.docx
 
Assignment 2 Discussion Question Strong corporate cultures have.docx
Assignment 2 Discussion Question Strong corporate cultures have.docxAssignment 2 Discussion Question Strong corporate cultures have.docx
Assignment 2 Discussion Question Strong corporate cultures have.docx
 

Recently uploaded

1029-Danh muc Sach Giao Khoa khoi 6.pdf
1029-Danh muc Sach Giao Khoa khoi  6.pdf1029-Danh muc Sach Giao Khoa khoi  6.pdf
1029-Danh muc Sach Giao Khoa khoi 6.pdf
QucHHunhnh
 
Activity 01 - Artificial Culture (1).pdf
Activity 01 - Artificial Culture (1).pdfActivity 01 - Artificial Culture (1).pdf
Activity 01 - Artificial Culture (1).pdf
ciinovamais
 
Making and Justifying Mathematical Decisions.pdf
Making and Justifying Mathematical Decisions.pdfMaking and Justifying Mathematical Decisions.pdf
Making and Justifying Mathematical Decisions.pdf
Chris Hunter
 
An Overview of Mutual Funds Bcom Project.pdf
An Overview of Mutual Funds Bcom Project.pdfAn Overview of Mutual Funds Bcom Project.pdf
An Overview of Mutual Funds Bcom Project.pdf
SanaAli374401
 

Recently uploaded (20)

Accessible design: Minimum effort, maximum impact
Accessible design: Minimum effort, maximum impactAccessible design: Minimum effort, maximum impact
Accessible design: Minimum effort, maximum impact
 
Basic Civil Engineering first year Notes- Chapter 4 Building.pptx
Basic Civil Engineering first year Notes- Chapter 4 Building.pptxBasic Civil Engineering first year Notes- Chapter 4 Building.pptx
Basic Civil Engineering first year Notes- Chapter 4 Building.pptx
 
microwave assisted reaction. General introduction
microwave assisted reaction. General introductionmicrowave assisted reaction. General introduction
microwave assisted reaction. General introduction
 
PROCESS RECORDING FORMAT.docx
PROCESS      RECORDING        FORMAT.docxPROCESS      RECORDING        FORMAT.docx
PROCESS RECORDING FORMAT.docx
 
1029-Danh muc Sach Giao Khoa khoi 6.pdf
1029-Danh muc Sach Giao Khoa khoi  6.pdf1029-Danh muc Sach Giao Khoa khoi  6.pdf
1029-Danh muc Sach Giao Khoa khoi 6.pdf
 
Application orientated numerical on hev.ppt
Application orientated numerical on hev.pptApplication orientated numerical on hev.ppt
Application orientated numerical on hev.ppt
 
Activity 01 - Artificial Culture (1).pdf
Activity 01 - Artificial Culture (1).pdfActivity 01 - Artificial Culture (1).pdf
Activity 01 - Artificial Culture (1).pdf
 
Class 11th Physics NEET formula sheet pdf
Class 11th Physics NEET formula sheet pdfClass 11th Physics NEET formula sheet pdf
Class 11th Physics NEET formula sheet pdf
 
Mattingly "AI & Prompt Design: The Basics of Prompt Design"
Mattingly "AI & Prompt Design: The Basics of Prompt Design"Mattingly "AI & Prompt Design: The Basics of Prompt Design"
Mattingly "AI & Prompt Design: The Basics of Prompt Design"
 
SECOND SEMESTER TOPIC COVERAGE SY 2023-2024 Trends, Networks, and Critical Th...
SECOND SEMESTER TOPIC COVERAGE SY 2023-2024 Trends, Networks, and Critical Th...SECOND SEMESTER TOPIC COVERAGE SY 2023-2024 Trends, Networks, and Critical Th...
SECOND SEMESTER TOPIC COVERAGE SY 2023-2024 Trends, Networks, and Critical Th...
 
Grant Readiness 101 TechSoup and Remy Consulting
Grant Readiness 101 TechSoup and Remy ConsultingGrant Readiness 101 TechSoup and Remy Consulting
Grant Readiness 101 TechSoup and Remy Consulting
 
Mattingly "AI & Prompt Design: Structured Data, Assistants, & RAG"
Mattingly "AI & Prompt Design: Structured Data, Assistants, & RAG"Mattingly "AI & Prompt Design: Structured Data, Assistants, & RAG"
Mattingly "AI & Prompt Design: Structured Data, Assistants, & RAG"
 
Introduction to Nonprofit Accounting: The Basics
Introduction to Nonprofit Accounting: The BasicsIntroduction to Nonprofit Accounting: The Basics
Introduction to Nonprofit Accounting: The Basics
 
Z Score,T Score, Percential Rank and Box Plot Graph
Z Score,T Score, Percential Rank and Box Plot GraphZ Score,T Score, Percential Rank and Box Plot Graph
Z Score,T Score, Percential Rank and Box Plot Graph
 
Advance Mobile Application Development class 07
Advance Mobile Application Development class 07Advance Mobile Application Development class 07
Advance Mobile Application Development class 07
 
Key note speaker Neum_Admir Softic_ENG.pdf
Key note speaker Neum_Admir Softic_ENG.pdfKey note speaker Neum_Admir Softic_ENG.pdf
Key note speaker Neum_Admir Softic_ENG.pdf
 
Making and Justifying Mathematical Decisions.pdf
Making and Justifying Mathematical Decisions.pdfMaking and Justifying Mathematical Decisions.pdf
Making and Justifying Mathematical Decisions.pdf
 
How to Give a Domain for a Field in Odoo 17
How to Give a Domain for a Field in Odoo 17How to Give a Domain for a Field in Odoo 17
How to Give a Domain for a Field in Odoo 17
 
Mehran University Newsletter Vol-X, Issue-I, 2024
Mehran University Newsletter Vol-X, Issue-I, 2024Mehran University Newsletter Vol-X, Issue-I, 2024
Mehran University Newsletter Vol-X, Issue-I, 2024
 
An Overview of Mutual Funds Bcom Project.pdf
An Overview of Mutual Funds Bcom Project.pdfAn Overview of Mutual Funds Bcom Project.pdf
An Overview of Mutual Funds Bcom Project.pdf
 

Copyright © 2005 by the author(s). Published here under licens.docx

  • 1. Copyright © 2005 by the author(s). Published here under license by the Resilience Alliance. Cinner, J. 2005. Socioeconomic factors influencing customary marine tenure in the Indo-Pacific. Ecology and Society 10(1): 36. [online] URL: http://www.ecologyandsociety.org/vol10/iss1/art36/ Research Socioeconomic factors influencing customary marine tenure in the Indo-Pacific Joshua Cinner1 ABSTRACT. For generations communities in the Western Pacific have employed a range of resource management techniques (including periodic reef closures, gear restrictions, entry limitations, and the protection of spawning aggregations) to limit marine resource use. Localized control over marine resources, commonly known as customary marine tenure (CMT), is the legal and cultural foundation for many of these practices. Because of their perceived potential to meet both conservation and community goals, these traditional resource management techniques are being revitalized by communities, governments, and NGOs as an integral part of national and regional marine conservation plans in the Pacific. However, the viability of conservation strategies built on a foundation of marine tenure may be in question, as it remains unclear whether marine tenure systems will be able to withstand the profound social and economic changes sweeping
  • 2. the Pacific region. Numerous studies have suggested that changes in marine tenure are attributed to social and economic factors, however, specific relationships between socioeconomic conditions and marine tenure are still not well understood. This paper examines the social and economic characteristics of 21 coastal communities in Papua New Guinea and Indonesia, and explores the characteristics of the communities that employ exclusive marine tenure to answer the following questions: Which socioeconomic factors are related to the presence of CMT regimes? How might socioeconomic factors influence the ability of communities to employ or maintain CMT regimes? Distance to market, immigration, dependence on fishing, and conflicts were found to be related to the presence of highly exclusive marine tenure systems. Exploring these relationships will help conservation practitioners better understand how future social changes may influence the foundation of conservation and development projects. Key Words: customary marine tenure; common-property; socioeconomic; Papua New Guinea; Indonesia. INTRODUCTION Contrary to Western society's propensity toward managing marine resources as open-access situations, another paradigm of common ocean governance called Customary Marine Tenure (CMT) is prevalent in parts of the Pacific. Under CMT, access to inshore marine resources is generally controlled by social units including individuals, families, clans or other kinship-based institutions, and villages (Carrier 1987, Ward 1997). These marine tenure institutions can range from relatively simple communally-owned marine areas
  • 3. from which outsiders are excluded to the complex and overlapping system of individual and family rights to space, species, gear, and even specific techniques of using gear described by Carrier (1987) and Cinner et al. (in press a) in the Manus province of Papua New Guinea (PNG). Although CMT has been documented throughout the World (Hviding 1996), it has reached the highest level of development in the Western Pacific (Ruddle and Akimichi 1984), including Japan (Ruddle 1985), Melanesia (Malinowski 1935, Hviding 1983, 1996, Wright 1985, Carrier 1987, Aswani 1999, 2002, Cooke et al. 2000, Foale and Macintyre 2000, Hickey and Johannes 2002), Polynesia (Hoffmann 2002), Micronesia (Johannes 1981, Zann 1985), Indonesia (Polunin 1984, Mantjoro 1996, Ruttan 1998, Harkes and Novaczek 2002), and Australia (Johannes and MacFarlane 1984). Legal recognition of marine tenure regimes can vary significantly 1James Cook University http://www.ecologyandsociety.org/vol10/iss1/art36/ mailto:[email protected] Ecology and Society 10(1): 36 http://www.ecologyandsociety.org/vol10/iss1/art36/ between countries. For example, in PNG customary ownership of marine resources is formally recognized in the constitution (Hyndman 1993). Alternatively, much of neighboring Indonesia is open-access. However, in some northern and eastern regions of Indonesia (i.e., parts of Muluku,
  • 4. North Sulawesi, and West Papua provinces), de facto marine tenure systems still govern local access to marine resources (see Polunin 1984, Mantjoro 1996, Ruttan 1998, Harkes and Novaczek 2002). In response to the degradation of inshore marine resources in many Pacific countries, governments and conservation groups are examining whether and how CMT regimes can be integrated into the modern conservation context (Cooke et al. 2000, Hoffmann 2002, Johannes 2002). CMT is particularly important in the context of resource management because it can serve as the legal and cultural foundation for other taboos such as gear prohibitions and spatial restrictions (Ruddle 1998, Aswani and Hamilton 2004). Where CMT is recognized, the highly decentralized authority over marine resources can also facilitate rapid adaptive response to changes in ecological or social conditions because decisions about limiting resource use can be made without the process of involving a centralized bureaucracy. Basing resource conservation initiatives around marine tenure regimes is particularly attractive to conservation organizations and donors because enforcement of specific fishing regulations within a tenure is generally the responsibility of the resource owner (Asafu-Adjaye 2000). By empowering community self-enforcement of fisheries regulations, CMT may provide a cost- effective means to reduce the burden on government intervention, regulation, and enforcement (Johannes 1981, Hviding 1996, Ruddle 1998). This is particularly important in the economic context of the Pacific where fisheries departments are typically understaffed and under-funded (Johannes 1981).
  • 5. Customary tenure regimes are the foundation of marine governance in much of the Pacific, but they must be better understood if they are to be effectively incorporated in resource management and development initiatives. In particular, very little is known about the social and economic frameworks that allow communities to employ or maintain CMT regimes. An array of theoretical and empirical research has shown that common property governance systems can be affected by socioeconomic factors such as religious or cultural homogeneity (Ostrom 1990), market influences (Hviding 1996, Henrich et al. 2001), transaction costs of decision-making (Ostrom 1990, Sumalde 2004), dependence on resources (Lise 2000, Agrawal 2001, Zanetell and Knuth 2004), social capital (Pretty and Ward 2001, Pretty 2003, Pretty and Smith 2004), conflicts (Polunin 1984, Adams et al. 2003) settlement patterns (Aswani 2002, Aswani and Hamilton 2004), and resource variability (see Agrawal 2002 for a comprehensive review of the factors influencing the emergence and successful functioning of common property institutions). The studies specific to CMT suggest that many of these social and economic factors can influence the nature and function of marine tenure institutions (Pollnac 1984, Polunin 1984, Baines 1989, Watson 1989, Hviding 1996, Cooke et al. 2000, Foale and Macintyre 2000, Aswani 2002), although specific relationships between socioeconomic conditions and CMT are sometimes contradictory and are still not well understood. For example, Watson (1989) discusses how changing socioeconomic conditions can render resource management
  • 6. strategies ineffective and inappropriate. Alternatively, Hviding (1996) documents how marine tenure rules became more exclusive for both commercial and subsistence activities in the Morovo Lagoon in response to increased prices of particular shells. Here I ask the following questions: Which socioeconomic factors are related to the presence of CMT regimes? How might these socioeconomic factors influence the ability of communities to employ or maintain CMT regimes? To date, most research examining the social, economic, and cultural factors influencing CMT has utilized a relatively small number of cases or examined these issues over a very limited geographical area. Despite the important contributions that small n case studies have made toward understanding CMT regimes, a fundamental limitation of this approach is that it does not allow us to discern larger patterns in how CMT regimes may respond to social and economic factors over a wider geographical context. In this paper, I seek to complement the more detailed case studies on the subject by using a comparative approach to examine the potential socioeconomic factors influencing viable CMT institutions in 21 coastal communities in Papua New Guinea and Indonesia. http://www.ecologyandsociety.org/vol10/iss1/art36/ Ecology and Society 10(1): 36 http://www.ecologyandsociety.org/vol10/iss1/art36/ METHODS
  • 7. Data collection Between October 2001 and January 2003, research was conducted in 15 villages in Papua New Guinea (PNG) and six villages in North Sulawesi, Indonesia (Fig. 1). A number of criteria were used to select the study sites. Research was conducted as part of an interdisciplinary Wildlife Conservation Society project that assessed the effectiveness of coral reef conservation in the Indo-Pacific (Cinner et al. 2003; Cinner et al. in press b, McClanahan et al. unpublished data). Agrawal (2001, 2002) suggests that purposively selecting sites that have variation in theoretically significant variables is a defensible sampling methodology in a common-property research context. Study sites were purposively selected to encompass a wide range of social, economic, demographic, and resource governance conditions (e.g., varying degrees of remoteness, marine tenure, market influence, dependence on marine resources, etc.). However, as a result of the project's intent to integrate both socioeconomic and ecological data, site selection was constrained somewhat by the need to have comparable ecological parameters at each site (coral reef habitat, current regimes, exposure, etc.), access to SCUBA facilities (although live onboard dive boats were used to access two remote study sites in PNG and two in Indonesia), and project goals of examining several specific conservation sites of regional importance (e.g., Bunaken and Kilu). Based on the fact that the villages were not randomly selected, a cautious approach to interpreting the results would suggest that the conclusions drawn from this study are not necessarily applicable outside of the study sites.
  • 8. Research was conducted over an one to three week period per village using one to four trained local assistants to aid in data collection. I used theoretical and empirical research (e.g., Ostrom 1990, Carrier and Carrier 1991, Agrawal 2001, Aswani 2002; Pollnac and Johnson in press) and socioeconomic assessment methodologies designed for coastal communities (Pollnac 1998, Bunce et al. 2000, Pollnac and Crawford 2000) to select indicators that were expected to be related to marine resource governance in the Indo-Pacific and that were also feasible to collect during the limited research time at each site. These were: population, distance to markets, the percentage of fish bartered or sold in the market, the type of settlement pattern, dependence on marine resources, immigration, the presence of conflicts over marine resources, and the exclusivity of marine tenure regimes. A combination of systematic household surveys (for example, surveying every second or third household), semi-structured interviews with key informants (community leaders and resource users), recording of oral histories, transect walks (walking through the community with a local to identify and verify issues), participant observations, descriptions of daily and seasonal time-use, women’s focus groups, and analyses of secondary sources such as population censuses and fisheries records were all used to gather information and triangulate results. A total of 954 household surveys were collected. Sampling within villages was based on a systematic sample design, where a sampling fraction of every ith house (e.g. 2nd, 3rd, 4th) was determined by
  • 9. dividing the total village population by the sample size (Henry 1990, de Vaus 1991). Variance from the systematic sample was assumed to be equal to the estimated variance based on a simple random sample (Scheaffer et al. 1996). The number of surveys per community ranged from 15-84 (Table 1), depending largely on the population of the village, the number of available research assistants, and the available time per site (this was influenced by factors such as weather, the availability and frequency of transportation to certain sites, and budget requirements such as the cost of the boat used to access remote sites). The head of the household was interviewed. If the head of the household was not available, the household was revisited later. If the head of the household was still not available, another adult from the household was interviewed. The head of the household could have been either a male or female. In instances where it was appropriate, more than one member of the household was interviewed to obtain the most accurate information about specific subjects (for example, if a female headed the house but her eldest son was more knowledgeable about the household's fishing activities and practices, then he would be asked about the proportion of fish catch bartered or sold). Household surveys were used to gather the following indicators: dependence on fishing, immigration, population of the village, and the percentage of fish sold in the market. Dependence http://www.ecologyandsociety.org/vol10/iss1/art36/
  • 10. Ecology and Society 10(1): 36 http://www.ecologyandsociety.org/vol10/iss1/art36/ Fig. 1. Map of study sites. on fishing was determined by having respondents list all the occupations the household engaged in for food or money. Respondents were then asked to rank these activities in order of importance. Those who regularly engaged in fishing estimated the percentage of their fish catch sold or bartered. Respondents were asked where they were from and were considered immigrants if they came from another village. Population was determined by: (1) counting the number of houses, (2) determining the average number of persons per household (adults and children) from the household surveys, and (3) multiplying this by the number of houses in the community. This was thought to be more accurate than relying on census information because the census record in one community reported almost twice as many houses as were actually counted. Key informants were selected using non-probability sampling techniques, including convenience sampling (for example, a respondent may be approached during resource use activities) or snowball sampling (where community members will suggest appropriate respondents) (Henry 1990). Between two and fifteen key informants were interviewed per village. Key informants also provided information on how exclusive the marine tenure was. Based on the key informant interviews
  • 11. http://www.ecologyandsociety.org/vol10/iss1/art36/ Ecology and Society 10(1): 36 http://www.ecologyandsociety.org/vol10/iss1/art36/ Table 1. Summary of study sites. Village Exclude non-own- ers Settlement pattern Conflicts over marine res- ources Population Distance to market (km) % immigrants % of fish bartered or sold % ranked fishing as
  • 12. primary occ- upation # of household surveys Ahus yes nucleated yes 544 21 3.9 68 77 51 Andra yes nucleated yes 479 31 13.6 75 55 44 Gabagaba yes nucleated yes 1708 58 2.6 66 51 38 Kakarotan yes nucleated yes 730 100 2.0 24 27 48 Madina yes dispersed no 564 70 35.0 13 0 32 Muluk yes nucleated yes 333 69 7.5 44 5 41 Para yes dispersed yes 1513 46 27.0 69 56 59 Airbanua no dispersed no 687 45 32.6 52 12 43 Blongko no nucleated no 1332 32 51.9 44 8 77 Bunaken no dispersed yes 3122 16 20.5 72 37 73 Enuk no nucleated no 272 14 27.3 64 24 33 Fissoa no dispersed no 287 85 14.0 18 0 31 Kapitu no dispersed no 1791 60 57.1 66 18 84 Kilu no dispersed no 584 17 25.0 31 0 40
  • 13. Kranget no nucleated no 2127 1 29.7 67 35 37 Mongol no nucleated no 493 0 64.3 35 18 28 Nusa Lik no nucleated no 273 1 46.2 69 54 15 Patanga no dispersed no 421 20 26.8 26 0 41 Riwo no dispersed no 1136 7 10.8 56 24 37 Tubuseria no nucleated no 5000 25 12.8 NA 18 61 Wadau no nucleated no 324 66 10.0 38 2 41 NA= not available and confirmed observations, villages were classified based on whether they: (1) practiced highly exclusive marine tenure regimes in which non-owners had to ask permission to access marine resources (classified as "strong" or "highly exclusive" marine tenure), or (2) had less exclusive or no marine tenure regimes in which non-owners regularly and openly accessed marine resources without asking permission (classified as "weak" or "less exclusive" marine tenure). Situations in which neighboring villages (non-owners) had been granted revocable use privileges and regularly accessed marine resources were also classified as less exclusive. Although this compartmentalization http://www.ecologyandsociety.org/vol10/iss1/art36/ Ecology and Society 10(1): 36
  • 14. http://www.ecologyandsociety.org/vol10/iss1/art36/ of a wide range of marine tenure regimes into comparable categories have undoubtedly lead to overly simplistic interpretations of their true complexities (Hviding 1996, McCay and Jentoft 1998), it is hoped that this will be outweighed by the ability to examine how marine tenure is related to different social and economic factors that can be captured best through a broader-scale comparative study. Key informants and secondary sources provided information on the presence of serious or significant conflicts over marine resources. I defined conflicts as intense verbal confrontations, use of violence, or court cases. Communities that reported conflicts over the previous 12 months or had court cases pending were considered to have conflicts. Key informants also provided information on the nearest market where marine products were regularly bought and sold. The distance from the village to markets were measured on topographic maps and nautical charts. Communities were grouped into two types of settlement patterns: dispersed or nucleated. Dispersed settlements were communities that were spread out and contained distinct sub-villages that were geographically separated. For example, the community of Riwo in Madang, PNG, had sub- villages on two separate islands and was thus considered a dispersed settlement. Nucleated settlements were communities that were relatively contiguous. Analyses
  • 15. The socioeconomic characteristics of communities that excluded all non-owners from accessing resources within their tenure were compared to the characteristics of communities where non-owners were allowed to access marine resources. Four types of analyses were performed to discern whether the presence of highly exclusive marine tenure was related to socioeconomic factors: the Mann Whitney U test, Fisher's Exact test, effect size, and statistical power. The SPSS 11.01 statistical program was used to determine statistical significance with the Mann- Whitney U and Fisher's Exact tests. The Mann- Whitney U test is a non-parametric alternative to the T-test, which is used to test whether two samples are independent (Siegel and Castellan 1988). The Mann-Whitney U test was used to examine whether ordinal or interval socioeconomic characteristics of communities with highly exclusive tenure were significantly different from communities with low excludability. For example, I used the Mann Whitney U test to compare the mean (rank of) percentage of immigrants in communities with highly exclusive marine tenure to the mean (rank of) percentage of immigrants in communities with weaker marine tenure. The frequency of dichotomous data (i.e., settlement patterns and the presence of conflicts) in communities with strong marine tenure was compared to communities with weak marine tenure using a Fisher’s Exact test. The Fisher’s Exact test is a non-parametric analysis used to discern whether two samples are independent based on the frequency of observed responses in a 2 x 2 contingency table with small independent
  • 16. samples (Siegel and Castellan 1988). Liberal p values were accepted for determining statistical significance (p<0.1), because this is an exploratory analysis and, based on the moderate sample size of 21 villages, I did not want to exclude any variables that might be important (i.e., I thought the consequences of committing a type I error were more grave than a type II error). To ensure national- level differences were not driving any of the patterns, significant differences between socioeconomic characteristics for Indonesian and New Guinean sites were tested for as well. Effect size is a standardized measure of the strength of the relationship between independent and dependent variables (Vaske et al. 2002). The Hedge's effect size was calculated as the difference between the mean socioeconomic conditions of the two groups (e.g., mean distance to market of the communities that employed exclusive marine tenure regimes minus the mean distance to market of the communities that did not) divided by the pooled standard deviation of both groups (Gliner et al. 2001). Statistical power is the probability of finding a statistically significant result when there is a real effect in the population being studied (i.e., rejecting the null hypothesis when a research hypothesis is true) (Cohen 1988). The power of these relationships was calculated using Statistica 6.0 statistical program. http://www.ecologyandsociety.org/vol10/iss1/art36/ Ecology and Society 10(1): 36
  • 17. http://www.ecologyandsociety.org/vol10/iss1/art36/ RESULTS Socioeconomic characteristics of communities The 21 communities varied considerably in the socioeconomic and governance indicators (Table 1). Communities ranged from small hamlets with only 272 people to large villages of 5,000 people. The importance of fishing as a livelihood strategy varied considerably in the communities examined. The percentage of households that ranked fishing as the primary occupation varied from 0-77%, with a mean of 25%. There was also a considerable range in the market influence (measured as distance to market and the percentage of fish bartered or sold) on the communities. Communities ranged from 0-100 km from markets. The mean distance to the nearest regular market for marine products for all sites was 37 km and the median distance was 32 km. The percentage of fish bartered or sold ranged from 13-72% and had a mean of 50%. The percentage of immigrants ranged from 2-64%, with a mean and median of 25%. Twelve of the 21 sites were nucleated settlements and only seven sites reported conflicts over marine resources. Seven of the 21 communities regularly excluded non-owners from accessing marine resources. High excludability occurred in the Sangihe-Talaud part of North Sulawesi, Indonesia ( Para and Kakarotan communities), but not the southern communities on or near the main island. In New Guinea, high excludability was reported throughout the country. Socioeconomic factors influencing marine
  • 18. tenure Only the population indicator differed significantly between the sites in New Guinea and Indonesia. The mean population for the New Guinean sites (970) was significantly lower than the mean population for the Indonesian sites (1530) (U = 17, p<0.05). This lack of difference between countries for other indicators suggests that national-level differences in marine tenure or socioeconomic conditions did not overly influence the analysis. Four out of seven variables differed significantly between villages with highly exclusive marine tenure and those with less exclusive tenure regimes (Table 2). The presence of conflicts over marine resources was correlated to the presence of highly exclusive marine tenure. The percentage of immigrants was lower in communities with exclusive marine tenure, the distance to market was higher in communities with exclusive marine tenure, and the percentage of households dependent on fishing was higher in communities with exclusive marine tenure (although this relationship was only significant at the p<0.1 level). The large effect size of these latter three relationships (d>0.93) suggests that substantial relationships exists (Vaske et al. 2002) (Table 2). No statistically significant differences were found in settlement pattern, population, or the percentage of fish sold in market between communities with strong and weak marine tenure. The effect size of the percentage of fish sold in markets (d=0.1) was very low, suggesting a minimal relationship (Vaske et al. 2002). However, the power of this relationship was also very low
  • 19. (0.05), so it would be difficult to detect differences. The effect size of population (d=0.37) was approaching a typical relationship found in the social sciences (d=0.5) (Vaske et al. 2002), and the power of this relationship was low (0.12) so the effect of population may have been real but not detectable with the sample size used. Note that effect sizes and power are not computed for dichotomous indicators (such as settlement pattern and conflicts). DISCUSSION This is one of the first studies to quantitatively explore relationships between socioeconomic factors and marine tenure over a large spatial scale with a moderate sample size. This paper found that communities with strong marine tenure were further from markets, had lower migration, but had higher dependence on fishing and conflicts over marine resources. This study is an important compliment to the more localized case studies and helps put such research into a broader context. For example, Aswani's comparison of marine tenure in the Roviana and Vonavona lagoons in the Solomon Islands provide a model for how socioeconomic and historical factors can result in three marine tenure patterns (Aswani 1999, 2002, Aswani and Hamilton 2004). Aswani's interpretations of how historical processes, socioeconomic factors, and demographic changes affect marine tenure in two coastal villages in the Solomon Islands suggest market forces and other exogenous pressures will not necessarily transform CMT institutions into open-access regimes (Aswani 1999, 2002). This study found that the distance to the market was negatively related to
  • 20. http://www.ecologyandsociety.org/vol10/iss1/art36/ Ecology and Society 10(1): 36 http://www.ecologyandsociety.org/vol10/iss1/art36/ Table 2. Differences in socioeconomic characteristics of communities with and without exclusive marine tenure. Variable Z score P Standardized effect size (d) Power Distance to marketA -2.24 0.03** 0.97 0.51 ImmigrationA -2.16 0.03** 0.97 0.51 Fishing as primary occupationA -1.69 0.09* 0.93 0.50 ConflictsB NA 0.001*** NA NA Percentage of fish sold in marketA -0.59 0.44 0.1 0.05 PopulationA 0 1 0.37 0.12 Settlement patternB NA 0.32 NA NA AComputed using Mann Whitney U test. BComputed using Fisher’s exact test. *** Indicates a statistically significant relationship at alpha?= 0.001
  • 21. ** Indicates a statistically significant relationship at alpha?= 0.05 * Indicates a statistically significant relationship at alpha?= 0.1 NA= not applicable because the variables were dichotomous. the exclusivity of marine tenure regimes, but whether the fishery was market or subsistence- based (measured in the percentage of fish bartered or sold) was not significant. This suggests that the strength of marine tenure institutions may be undermined by connectivity to larger markets, perhaps by introducing new ways of providing credit and generating prestige (Agrawal 2002). Commercial or market value for marine products, however, may not necessarily diminish the strength of tenure institutions. To date, conclusions about how heterogeneity influences the development and maintenance of common property institutions remain inconclusive. Heterogeneity (which can include the often interrelated economic, cultural, religious, and resource use differences in a society) has been shown to have positive, negative, or minimal effects on common property management (Ruttan and Borgerhoff Mulder 1999, Glaesel 2000, Pollnac et al. 2001, Bardhan and Dayton-Johnson 2002; Pollnac and Johnson in press). This study found a lower proportion of immigrants in communities with highly exclusive marine tenure institutions, which is consistent with notions of high social capital being an important component of maintaining common-property management regimes (Pretty 2003). Cultural heterogeneity associated with immigration may act to increase the transaction
  • 22. costs of developing, maintaining, and enforcing marine tenure regulations (Aswani and Hamilton 2004). Trust, reciprocal arrangements, and consistent norms are important components of social capital (Pretty and Smith 2004) that may be affected by a high proportion of immigrants. Likewise, immigrants may not perceive the rules, processes, and authorities governing marine tenure to be legitimate, and thus may not comply with established rules (Sutinen and Kuperan 1999). The relationship found between high dependence on marine resources and the exclusivity of marine tenure regimes is consistent with research on an array of common pool resources that suggests a positive relationship may exist between resource dependence and participation in common property arrangements (Lise 2000, Agrawal 2002, Zanetell http://www.ecologyandsociety.org/vol10/iss1/art36/ Ecology and Society 10(1): 36 http://www.ecologyandsociety.org/vol10/iss1/art36/ and Knuth 2004). Communities with high dependence on marine resources may employ exclusive marine tenure regimes to increase livelihood security. For example, the Andra and Ahus Island study sites in Manus, PNG, are small infertile islands surrounded by large (>5 km2) reef lagoons. Islanders have limited access to essential terrestrial resources (e.g., vegetables and firewood) and consequently their dependence on marine resources is very high (Cinner et al. in press a). These communities claim exclusive rights to marine
  • 23. resources on the reefs surrounding their islands and reefs along the coast of the main Manus Island (Carrier 1987, Carrier and Carrier 1989; Cinner et al. in press a), preventing mainland communities from accessing marine resources. These exclusive marine tenure regimes help to create an economic monopoly on marine resources among fishing communities (Malinowski 1935) and help to ensure that island communities have desirable goods to sell or trade in local markets (Carrier 1987; Cinner et al. in press a), thereby improving their livelihood security. There are several possible explanations for the relationship between the presence of conflicts and exclusive marine tenure regimes. Some researchers suggest that marine tenure regimes may have developed in response to conflicts and may serve to mitigate them (Pollnac 1984, Polunin 1984). On the other hand, the complexity of use rights associated with marine tenure institutions can cause them to be continually challenged (Foale and Macintyre 2000). In Indonesia, the lack of legal recognition of marine tenure also seemed to cause conflicts over marine resources. For example, while researching in Para Island, North Sulawesi, long-standing tenure rights were challenged by neighboring communities who claimed that exclusive tenure rights were not legal under Indonesia’s constitution and attempted to fish in Para's fishing grounds. The Para community responded by brandishing a firearm to chase off fishers from the other community. Interrelationships among indicators may also help to explain the relationship between conflicts and exclusive marine tenure regimes. For example, communities with exclusive marine tenure regimes (with high
  • 24. dependence on marine resources) used confiscation of fishing equipment, intimidation, and even violence to enforce their tenure. Communities with lower dependence on marine resources may find the additional livelihood security that might be gained from employing exclusive marine tenure is not worth engaging the conflicts associated with this type of territory defense. Several of the factors expected to be related to the presence of CMT did not demonstrate significant relationships, including population and settlement patterns. In a review of the factors influencing the sustainability of common property institutions, Agrawal (2002) notes that debates concerning the effect of population on common property institutions are highly polarized. Results from this study as to the effect of population on the presence of exclusive marine tenure regimes are inconclusive. The possibility exists that the sample size used here was too small to detect differences in these indicators, particularly considering the effect size for population was approaching a moderate effect. More interestingly though, is the possibility that the populations in the communities studied were too small to detect any effect. Gabagaba and Para were two of the five largest communities in my study (the 4th and 5th largest populations, respectively), but employed CMT (Table 1). These communities had populations of fewer than 2,000 and the largest population of any community studied was 5,000 residents. Harkes and Novaczek (2002) found that traditional management in Indonesia (called Sasi) dies out in villages greater than 3,000 people. However, Evans et al. (1997) noted that Sasi
  • 25. was present in a community larger than 14,000 people. Therefore, based on previous research, the critical population size at which CMT may cease to function effectively may not have been reached in this study (or reached by only the two sites with populations >3,000). The population levels of many of the study sites were similar to many rural coastal areas in the provinces studied (e.g., National Statistics Office 2002a, b), however, urbanized areas with high populations were not examined. An interesting area of further inquiry would be to examine whether or how communities with tens of thousands of residents could support highly exclusive marine tenure regimes. Aswani (2002), and Aswani and Hamilton (2004) also speculated that nucleated and dispersed settlement patterns influenced whether and how communities in the Solomon Islands could develop and maintain marine tenure regimes. Although this study was not able to explore in-depth ethnographic accounts of settlement histories, no relationship was found between settlement patterns and the strength of marine tenure institutions. In the broader context, this suggests that whether communities are nucleated or dispersed may be less important than other socioeconomic factors in maintaining marine http://www.ecologyandsociety.org/vol10/iss1/art36/ Ecology and Society 10(1): 36 http://www.ecologyandsociety.org/vol10/iss1/art36/ tenure regimes. One of the initial concerns with this study was that
  • 26. national or regional factors might overshadow the village level factors examined. However, this did not appear to be the case: there were few significant differences in socioeconomic characteristics between the two countries and several adjacent or nearby communities reported different marine tenure regimes, supporting the notion that marine tenure can vary in response to village-level factors and is not only a product of regional sociocultural influences. For example, Madina and Fissoa were nearby communities of a common language group, but Madina had high excludability and Fissoa had low excludability. Another potential concern was that intersite variability in the resource might have been very high, which could conceivably influence the nature of the marine tenure institutions. Incorporating the ecological criteria in site selection provided a reasonable assurance that relatively little variance existed in the resources within each tenure (i.e., the tenure areas all contain comparable coral reefs in similar ecological zones). Furthermore, we can infer from other analyses of the resources within these sites (Cinner et al. unpublished data; Cinner et al. in press-b; Cinner and McClanahan unpublished data) that many of the commercially valuable species harvested within the tenure sites such as trochus, beche de mer, and reef fish have small home ranges (e.g., on the scale of hectares to kilometers) (Kramer and Chapman 1999) congruent to the scale of the tenure areas. Therefore, the possible variance in resource conditions is expected to have relatively little influence in the observed tenure institutions. Speculation
  • 27. This study was able to tease out several indicators that were of more importance than others and provide qualitative descriptions of how these factors may be related to the presence of CMT. The limitations inherent in the non-random design of this study mean these results apply only to these study sites and should not be generalized to the wider region. Keeping in mind the limitations of this study's methodology, it is important to speculate on whether and how these regimes will be able to adapt and respond to changes in socioeconomic conditions. Marine tenure systems are dynamic institutions that, through adaptation to changing scenarios, have proven relatively robust to population pressures and aspects of economic and political modernization (Hviding 1998). However, Asia-Pacific is a region undergoing profound social, economic, and demographic changes (UNEP 2002), and there may be social forces that marine tenure regimes are unable to adapt to. Results from this study suggest that socioeconomic changes that will increase immigration, open new markets, and decrease dependence on marine resources may influence the ability of communities to employ or maintain exclusive marine tenure regimes. Under these scenarios, conservation and development strategies that rely on high excludability in a community's tenure may become challenged at their foundation. Alternatively, results from this study also suggest CMT may be somewhat resilient to other socioeconomic factors such as population growth. Highly exclusive CMT can operate in communities
  • 28. with populations of 1,700, but strong CMT is related to low levels of immigration. This suggests that high endogenous population growth (i.e., not from immigration) in smaller communities may not affect the ability to employ viable marine tenure. The next research challenge is to address the applicability of these results to the wider region. A random selection of villages that could be considered representative of the region would be desirable for future studies. Another research priority is determining what specific aspects of these variables influence marine tenure. For example, high immigration may cause confusion over use rights, disrupt traditional information exchange mechanisms, and/or introduce new ideas that challenge traditional practices. A better understanding of how these factors influence marine tenure regimes will allow development and conservation organizations to target capacity building and other activities to potentially increase the resilience of Pacific conservation strategies against the forces of social change. Responses to this article can be read online at: http://www.ecologyandsociety.org/vol10/iss1/art36/responses/ Acknowledgments: I thank the people and leaders of all 21 villages for http://www.ecologyandsociety.org/vol10/iss1/art36/ http://www.ecologyandsociety.org/vol10/iss1/art36/responses/ Ecology and Society 10(1): 36
  • 29. http://www.ecologyandsociety.org/vol10/iss1/art36/ allowing me to work in their communities. Thanks to LIPI, the PNG National Research Council, PNG Department of Environment and Conservation, and the PNG National Fisheries Authority. The David and Lucille Packard Foundation supported this research through the Wildlife Conservation Society. Thanks to S. Sutton, R. Arthur, J. Carrier, and three anonymous reviewers for reviewing this manuscript and providing extremely helpful and constructive comments. LITERATURE CITED Adams, W., D. Brockington, J. Dyson, and B. Vira. 2003. Managing tragedies: understanding conflict over common pool resources. Science 302:1915-1916. Agrawal, A. 2002. Common resources and institutional stability in E. Ostrom, T. Dietz, N. Dolsak, P. Stern, S. Stonich, and E. Weber, editors. The drama of the commons. National Academies Press, Washington, D.C., USA. Agrawal, A. 2001. Common property institutions and sustainable governance of resources. World Development 29:1649-1672. Asafu-Adjaye, J. 2000. Customary marine tenure systems and sustainable fisheries management in Papua New Guinea. International Journal of Socio Economics 27:917-926. Aswani, S., and R. Hamilton. 2004. Integrating
  • 30. indigenous ecological knowledge and customary sea tenure with marine science and social science for conservation of bumphead parrotfish (Bolbometopon muricatum) in the Roviana Lagoon, Solomon Islands. Environmental Conservation 31:69-83. Aswani, S. 2002. Assessing the effects of changing demographic and consumption patterns on sea tenure regimes in the Roviana Lagoon, Solomon Islands. AMBIO 31:272-284. Aswani, S. 1999. Common property models of sea tenure: a case study from the Roviana and Vonavona Lagoons, New Georgia, Solomon Islands. Human Ecology 27:417-453. Baines, G. 1989. Traditional resource management in the Melanesian South Pacific: a development dilemma. Pages 54-69 in F. Berkes, editor. Common property resources: ecology and community-based sustainable development. Belhaven Press, London, England. Bardhan, P., and J. Dayton-Johnson. 2002. Unequal irrigators in E. Ostrom, T. Dietz, N. Dolsak, P. Stern, S. Stonich, and E. Weber, editors. The drama of the commons. National Academies Press, Washington, D.C., USA. Bunce, L., P. Townsley, R. S. Pomeroy, and R. B. Pollnac. 2000. Socioeconomic manual for coral reef management. Australian Institute of Marine Science, Townsville, Australia. Carrier, J. 1987. Marine tenure and conservation in Papua New Guinea. Pages 143-167 in B. McCay,
  • 31. and J. Acheson, editors. The Question of the commons: the culture and ecology of common resources. The University of Arizona Press, Tucson, Arizona, USA. Carrier, J., and A. Carrier. 1991. Structure and process in a Melanesian society: Ponam's progress in the twentieth century. Harwood Academic Publishers, Paris, France. Carrier, J., and A. Carrier. 1989. Wage, trade, and exchange in Melanesia: a Manus society in the modern state. University of California Press, Berkeley, California, USA. Cinner, J., J. Ben, and M. Marnane. 2003. How socioeconomic monitoring can assist marine reserve management: Kimbe Bay, Papua New Guinea in C. Wilkinson, and A. Green, editors. Monitoring coral reef marine protected areas. Australian Institute for Marine Science, Townsville, Australia. Cinner, J., T. H. Clark, M. Marnane, T. McClanahan, and J. Ben. In press a. Trade, tenure, and tradition: influence of sociocultural factors on resource use in Melanesia. Conservation Biology. Cinner, J., M. Marnane, T. McClanahan, and T. H. Clark. In press b. Conservation and community benefits from traditional coral reef management at Ahus Island, Papua New Guinea. Conservation Biology. http://www.ecologyandsociety.org/vol10/iss1/art36/
  • 32. Ecology and Society 10(1): 36 http://www.ecologyandsociety.org/vol10/iss1/art36/ Cohen. 1988. Statistical Power Analysis for Behavioral Sciences. Lawrence Erlbaum Associates, Hillsdale, New Jersey, USA. Cooke, A. J., N. V. C. Polunin, and K. Moce. 2000. Comparative assessment of stakeholder management in traditional Fijian fishing-grounds. Environmental Conservation 27:291-299. de Vaus, D. A. 1991. Surveys in social research. UCL, London, England. Evans, S. M., M. E. Gill, A. S. W. Retraubun, J. Abrahamz, and J. Dangeubun. 1997. Traditional management practices and the conservation of the gastropod (Trochus nilitocus) and fish stocks in the Maluku Province (Eastern Indonesia). Fisheries Research 31:83-91. Foale, S., and M. Macintyre. 2000. Dynamic and flexible aspects of land and marine tenure at West Nggela: implications for marine resource management. Oceania 71:30-45. Glaesel, H. 2000. State and local resistance to the expansion of two environmentally harmful marine fishing techniques in Kenya. Society and Natural Resources 13:321-338. Gliner, J., G. Vaske, and G. Morgan. 2001. Null Hypothesis significance testing: effect size does matter. Human Dimensions of Wildlife 6:291-301.
  • 33. Harkes, I., and I. Novaczek. 2002. Presence, performance, and institutional resilience of sasi, a traditional management institution in Central Maluku, Indonesia. Ocean and Coastal Management 45:237-260. Henrich, J., R. Boyd, S. Bowles, H. Gintis, C. Camerer, F. Ernst, and R. McElreath. 2001. In search of homo economicus: behavioral experiments in fifteen small-scale societies. American Economic Review 91:73-78. Henry, G. T. 1990. Practical sampling. Sage Publications, Newbury Park, California, USA. Hickey, F., and Johannes, R. E. 2002. Recent evolution of village-based marine resource management in Vanuatu. SPC Traditional Management Bulletin 14:8-21. Hoffmann, T. C. 2002. The reimplementation of the Ra'ui: coral reef management in Rarotonga, Cook Islands. Coastal Management 30:401-418. Hviding, E. 1998. Contextual flexibility: present status and future of customary marine tenure in Solomon Islands. Ocean and Coastal Management 40:253-269. Hviding, E. 1996. Guardians of the Marovo Lagoon: Practice, place, and politics in maritime Melanesia. University Press of Hawai'i, Honolulu, Hawaii, USA. Hviding, E. 1983. Keeping the sea: aspects of
  • 34. marine tenure in Marovo lagoon, Solomon Islands. Pages 9-44 in K. Ruddle, and R. E. Johannes, editors. Traditional marine resource management in the Pacific Basin: an anthology. UNESCO, Jakarta, Indonesia. Hyndman, D. 1993. Sea tenure and the management of living marine resources in Papua New Guinea. Pacific Studies 16:99-114. Johannes, R. E. 2002. The renaissance of community-based marine resource management in Oceania. Annual Review of Ecological Systems 33:317-340. Johannes, R. E. 1981. Words of the lagoon: fishing and marine lore in the Palau district of Micronesia. University of California Press, Berkeley, California, USA. Johannes, R. E., and J. W. MacFarlane. 1984. Territorial sea rights in the Torres Strait Islands with emphasis on Murry Island in K. Ruddle, and T. Akimichi, editors. Maritime institutions in the Western Pacific. National Museum of Ethnology, Osaka, Japan. Kramer, D. L., and M. R. Chapman. 1999. Implications of fish home range size and relocation for marine reserve function. Environmental Biology of Fishes 55:65-79. Lise, W. 2000. Factors influencing people's participation in forest management in India. Ecological Economics 34:379-392.
  • 35. Malinowski, B. 1935. Coral gardens and their magic. George Allen and Unwin, London, England. http://www.ecologyandsociety.org/vol10/iss1/art36/ Ecology and Society 10(1): 36 http://www.ecologyandsociety.org/vol10/iss1/art36/ Mantjoro, E. 1996. Management of traditional common fishing grounds: the experience of the Para community, Indonesia. Coastal Management 24:229-250. McCay, B., and S. Jentoft. 1998. Market or community failure: critical perspectives on common property research. Human Organization 57:21-29. National Statistics Office. 2002a. Census unit register: Madang province. National Statistics Office, Port Moresby. National Statistics Office. 2002b. Census unit register: Manus province. National Statistics Office, Port Moresby. Ostrom, E. 1990. Governing the commons: the evolution of institutions for collective action. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, United Kingdom. Pollnac, R. B. 1998. Rapid assessment of management parameters for coral reefs. University of Rhode Island, Coastal Resources Center, Narragansett, Rhode Island, USA.
  • 36. Pollnac, R. B. 1984. Investigating territorial use rights among fishermen. Pages 267-284 in K. Ruddle, and T. Akimichi, editors. Maritime Institutions in the Western Pacific. National Museum of Ethnology, Osaka, Japan. Pollnac, R. B., and B. Crawford. 2000. Assessing behavioral aspects of coastal resource use. Coastal Resources Center, University of Rhode Island, Narragansett, Rhode Island, USA. Pollnac, R. B., B. R. Crawford, and M. Gorospe. 2001. Discovering factors that influence the success of community-based marine protected areas in the Visayas, Philippines. Ocean and Coastal Management 44:683-710. Pollnac, R. B., and J. C. Johnson. In press. Folk management and conservation of marine resources: towards a theoretical and methodological assessment in N. Kishigami, and J. Savelle, editors. Indigenous use and management of marine resources. National Museum of Ethnology, Osaka, Japan. Polunin, N. V. C. 1984. Do traditional marine "reserves" conserve? A view of Indonesian and New Guinean evidence. Pages 267-284 in K. Ruddle, and T. Akimichi, editors. Maritime institutions in the Western Pacific. National Museum of Ethnology, Osaka, Japan. Pretty, J. 2003. Social capital and the collective management of resources. Science 302:1912-1914.
  • 37. Pretty, J., and D. Smith. 2004. Social capital in biodiversity conservation and management. Conservation Biology 18:631-638. Pretty, J., and H. Ward. 2001. Social capital and the environment. World Development 29:209-227. Ruddle, K. 1998. The context of policy design for existing community-based fisheries management in the Pacific Islands. Ocean and Coastal Management 40:105-126. Ruddle, K. 1985. The continuity of traditional management practices: the case of Japanese coastal fishing. Pages 159-179 in K. Ruddle, and R. E. Johannes, editors. The traditional knowledge and management of coastal systems in Asia and the Pacific. United Nations Environmental and Cultural Organization, Jakarta Pusat, Indonesia. Ruddle, K., and T. Akimichi. 1984. Introduction in K. Ruddle, and T. Akimichi, editors. Maritime institutions in the Western Pacific. National Museum of Ethnology, Osaka, Japan. Ruttan, L. M. 1998. Closing the commons: cooperation for gain or restraint? Human Ecology 26:43-66. Ruttan, L. M., and M. Borgerhoff Mulder. 1999. Are East African pastoralists truly conservationists? Current Anthropology 40:621-652. Scheaffer, R. L., W. I. Mendenhall, and L. Ott. 1996. Elementary survey sampling. Wadsworth, Belmont, California, USA.
  • 38. Siegel, S., and N. J. Castellan. 1988. Nonparametric statistics for the behavioral sciences. McGraw-Hill, New York, USA. Sumalde, Z. 2004. Transaction costs of community-based coastal resource management: the case of San Miguel Bay, Philippines. Coastal Management 32:51-60. http://www.ecologyandsociety.org/vol10/iss1/art36/ Ecology and Society 10(1): 36 http://www.ecologyandsociety.org/vol10/iss1/art36/ Sutinen, J. G., and K. Kuperan. 1999. A socio- economic theory of regulatory compliance. International Journal of Socio Economics 26:174-193. UNEP. 2002. Global environmental outlook 3: past, present, and future perspectives. Earthscan Publications Ltd., London, England. Vaske, G., J. Gliner, and G. Morgan. 2002. Communicating judgements about practical significance: effect size, confidence intervals, and odds ratios. Human Dimensions of Wildlife 7:287-300. Ward, G. R. 1997. Changing forms of communal tenure. Page 13 in P. Larmour, editor. The governance of common property in the Pacific Region. National Centre for Development Studies, Australian Nation University, Canberra, Australia.
  • 39. Watson, D. 1989. The evolution of appropriate resource-management systems. Pages 54-69 in F. Berkes, editor. Common property resources: Ecology and community-based sustainable development. Belhaven Press, London, England. Wright, A. 1985. Marine resource use in Papua New Guinea: can traditional concepts and contemporary development be integrated? Pages 53-77 in K. Ruddle, and R. E. Johannes, editors. The traditional knowledge and management of coastal systems in Asia and the Pacific. United Nations Educational, Scientific, and Cultural Organization, Jakarta Pusat, Indonesia. Zanetell, B. A., and B. A. Knuth. 2004. Participation rhetoric or community-based management reality? Influences on willingness to participate in a Venezuelan freshwater fishery. World Development 32:793-807. Zann, L. P. 1985. Traditional management and conservation of fisheries in Kiribati and Tuvalu atolls. Pages 53-77 in K. Ruddle, and R. E. Johannes, editors. The traditional knowledge and management of coastal systems in Asia and the Pacific. United Nations Environmental and Cultural Organization, Jakarta Pusat, Indonesia. http://www.ecologyandsociety.org/vol10/iss1/art36/TitleAbstrac tIntroductionMethodsData collectionAnalysesResultsSocioeconomic characteristics of communitiesSocioeconomic factors influencing marine tenureDiscussionSpeculationResponses to this articleAcknowledgmentsLiterature citedFigure1Table1Table2
  • 40. THE MANAGEMENT OF COMMON PROPERTY RESOURCES: Finding a Cooperative Solution Robert W hen will villagers come together to produce goods and ser- vices that they all need but cannot provide individually? In what circumstances will those who face a potential "tragedy of the commons" be able to formulate rules by which the tragedy is averted? Many writers on collective action are inclined to think that the circumstances are very limited. They argue that people in a situation
  • 41. in which all could benefit from cooperation will be unlikely to coop- erate without an external agent to enforce agreements. Likewise, many theorists on property rights argue that common property re- sources will be overexploited as demand rises, so only private enclo- sure or state regulation stands a chance of preventing such a result.1 This article offers a critique of some of the analytical arguments used to reach these conclusions and argues that they have been inappro- priately applied to certain types of village resources. It then discusses how to judge whether villagers will be able to sustain local rules of restrained access to common property resources and interprets the evidence from a study of forty-one villages in South India. Clearly there can be no general presumption that collective action
  • 42. rather than privatization or state regulation will work: witness the frequency of degraded grazing commons, despoiled forests, overex- ploited groundwater, and depleted fisheries. But there are many exam- ples of villagers collectively managing property for long periods. Pri- vatization or state regulation is therefore not always essential. A third option—local collective action—needs to be taken seriously. Because © 1 9 8 7 The International Bank for Reconstruction and Development/The World Bank 219 less public money is likely to be needed for local collective action than for either privatization or state regulation, it makes financial sense to establish local rules where circumstances permit. Common
  • 43. Property and Common-Pool Resources On a continuum of property rights, exclusive possession (freehold) is at one end. At the other is no property, as in ocean fisheries or the atmosphere. In between lies common property, where the rights to exploit a resource are held by people in conjunction with each other. These rights may take several forms: they may allow unlimited exploi- tation for those within a specified group (as happened in commercial fisheries under national jurisdiction) or they may stipulate limits for each user (as in most commercial fisheries today or as in "stinting" of a grazing commons). Of course, the same type of resource may be exploited under a variety of property rights. This article deals with those
  • 44. resources that might be called "common-pool" resources—a subset of public goods, as that term is used in economics. All public goods have the property that many people can use them at once, because exclusion is difficult. But some public goods yield infinite benefits, in the sense that if A uses more there is not less available for others (lighthouses and weath- er forecasts, for example). Common-pool resources, by contrast, are public goods with finite, or subtractive, benefits: if A uses more, less remains for others. Common-pool resources are therefore potentially subject to congestion, depletion, or degradation (Blomquist and Os- trom 1985; Randall 1983). Groundwater is an obvious example of a common-pool resource. It can be used jointly, but use is subtractive. So when water is scarce,
  • 45. the groundwater table is likely to be depleted. Canal irrigation water, unfenced grazing land, and unfenced forest all meet the same criteria. These three resources—water, grazing, and trees—are vital to the livelihoods of millions of people in developing countries; the question of how to prevent their overexploitation as population grows is im- portant for development policy. The prevailing answer runs as follows: when people are in a situa- tion where they could mutually benefit if all of them restrained their use of a common-pool resource, they will not do so unless an external agency enforces a suitable rule. Each individual has an incentive to ignore the social costs of his behavior for fear that others will exploit the resource before he does. As a result, the rate of aggregate use exceeds the physical or biological rate at which the resource
  • 46. renews itself (Ostrom 1985b). This argument has been used to justify far-reaching proposals for changing the way that common-pool resources are managed (Ostrom 1985a; Runge 1986). According to one school, full private property 220 Research Observer 2, no. 2 (July 1987) rights over the commons are a necessary condition for avoiding over- exploitation (Demsetz 1967; North and Thomas 1977; Johnson 1972; Picardi and Siefert 1976). According to another, it is essential to give an external agency—usually the state—full authority to regulate the commons (Carruthers and Stoner 1981; Hardin 1968). For both schools, the policy issue is simply how to achieve the desired change
  • 47. with the least opposition from those involved. Defining the conditions under which users of common-pool re- sources may voluntarily restrain their use can be considered as a subproblem of the theory of collective action, also known as the theory of public goods. Collective action is action by more than one person intended to achieve a common goal or satisfy a common interest (that is, a goal or interest that cannot be obtained by an individual alone). Achievement means that a public or collective good has been provided. The collective action might be setting and observ- ing a rule of restrained access to a common-pool resource, and the public good might be the sustainable exploitation that results. One of the theories that has generated pessimism about the viability of collective action is Mancur Olson's "logic of collective action" (which might better be called the illogic of collective action, or the logic of collective inaction). His core proposition is this: "unless there
  • 48. is coercion or some other special device to make individuals act in their common interest, rational, self-interested individuals will not act to achieve their common or group interests" (Olson 1971, emphasis added). In other words, the theorem says that (a) voluntary collective action will not produce public goods, and (b) collective action based on selective (that is, excludable) penalties or rewards may produce public goods. Existing cases of common interest groups are thus to be explained by selective punishments or inducements. My findings question this argument. Theories of Collective Action The conventional view of Indian villages is that they lack any real
  • 49. public realm. A number of men are regarded as "big men," in some sense first in the village. But there is no clearly defined social domain or institution separate from state authority where activities of a public nature are carried out, no center of community management other than the lowest levels of the state apparatus itself, and no machinery for raising resources for public (village) purposes other than through state-sanctioned taxation. I analyzed forty-one villages in South India (Kurnool district, An- dhra Pradesh), thirty-one of which are irrigated from one or another of two large canal systems, while the other ten are dry. Despite the Indian Villages Robert Wade 221
  • 50. conventional view to the contrary, a significant number of these vil- lages do provide public goods and services through local arrange- ments that have nothing to do with outside bodies, whether govern- ment or voluntary agencies. The Public Kurnool district is semiarid; rainfall averages 620 millimeters a year Realm m a u m m o d a l distribution. Population density averages 105 people a square kilometer (1971), up from 53 in 1870. Seventy percent of the cultivated area is under foodcrops; only 12 percent is irrigated. Thirty-four percent of villages are supplied with electricity (1971). There is one tractor for every one or two irrigated villages, and many fewer in rainfed villages (1980). Most variation in real wage rates is
  • 51. contained within the range of 1.5 to 4.5 kilograms of foodgrain a day. In those villages that have a public realm, it consists of four main institutions: a village council (distinct from the statutory Panchayat, which is moribund in all the forty-one villages); a village standing fund (distinct from local government moneys); a group of village guards, employed by the council to protect crops from livestock and thieves; and a group of "common irrigators," employed by the council to distribute water to the rice fields and to help get more water to the village through the government-run canal. The council, and through it the field guards and common irrigators, are loosely accountable to an annual meeting of all the village's farmers. The council also organizes the supply of many other public goods
  • 52. and services, such as repairing wells, ridding the village of monkeys, and making donations for a new primary school or a building where sick animals can be treated, and so on. All these services except water distribution are financed from the village standing fund, for which the council raises money in a variety of ways. Take K village as an example. Its population is just over 3,000. The council has about nine members (the number is fixed for any one year, but varies slightly from year to year). It has authority to make deci- sions affecting all the village. The village's standing fund spends about Rs 10,000 a year (in an economy where a male agricultural laborer gets Rs 4 a day outside of seasonal peaks). The standing fund pays the salaries of the field guards. Four are employed full-time for most of the year, and another two to four are added as the harvest
  • 53. approach- es. About twelve common irrigators are employed for up to two and a half months, for about 1,200 acres of first-season rice. At harvest the common irrigators supplement the field guards in protecting the crops. In the sample of thirty-one canal-irrigated villages, eight have all four of the main corporate institutions—council, fund, field guards, and common irrigators; eleven have some but not all; and twelve have 222 Research Observer 2, no. 2 (July 1987) none. These proportions are not necessarily typical of the whole area, since the sample was drawn not randomly but with an eye to ease of access and a representative range of water arrangements.
  • 54. Among the ten dry villages, eight have field guards; six have a village council; and six have a village fund. The impetus for central (village) control comes primarily from two distinct sources of social conflict and production loss. Trespassing animals and thieves are one. Unrestrained use of irrigation water is the other. These are discussed in turn, using K village as an example. K has a population density of 159 people a square kilometer. With this density goes a farming system of annual cropping (at least one crop on each plot each year) and multiple cropping where irrigation permits. Little waste or yearly fallow land is left; the village has no common, in the sense of a large area available for common grazing for a year or more. But oxen and buffalo are needed for traction,
  • 55. and they must be fed. During the growing season they graze close to the crops, on the verges or on small areas of fallow, which are treated as commons. Because fields are not fenced, the animals must be tethered or shepherded. But the incentives for careful shepherding or tethering are asymmetrical—I may not be unhappy to see my animals get fat on your grain. The rationale of the field guards is to make the incentives less asymmetrical. During the medieval and early modern period in Europe, the open-field system solved the problem primarily by regu- lating the cropping; these Indian villagers solve it mainly by regulating the livestock. If the field guards catch an animal grazing a standing crop, they take it to the village pound, where it remains until its owner pays a fine. If just a few animals are involved, the fine is a flat rate—
  • 56. Rs 2 per animal during the day, Rs 4 at night. The rate is set by the council; the field guards collect and keep the fine, dividing it equally among themselves. If many animals are involved, the council uses its discre- tion. The fine may run into hundreds of rupees. The field guards collect it, keep 25 percent, and hand the rest over to the standing fund. (In most villages the owner of the damaged crop is not compen- sated.) The field guards do not enforce a stinting. The decision about how many animals to own and graze is left to each individual. After the harvest of most of the rainfed crops in February, large areas of stubble become available for grazing. (Even in irrigated vil- lages, the area under rainfed crops is generally greater than the irri- gated area.) Each landowner could reserve his stubble for his own animals or those he chose to allow. He could do so by posting guards
  • 57. around each field or by fencing. But the cost of either method— the cost of privatizing the stubble—is very high; all the more so as each The Management of Grazing Robert Wade 223 landowner tends to have his holding divided into several scattered plots (McCloskey 1975). So, as in the open-field system of Europe, the stubble is put in common; private rights to the product of the land extend only to the crop, not to the crop residues. How, in the "corporate" villages, is this commons managed? Since the village's own stock of animals is adjusted to the availability
  • 58. of year-round grazing, after the harvest it has some surplus grazing, which it could rent out to herdsmen from drier parts of the district. The market for grazing and manure is organized in two ways. In one system, a small group of herders bargains with the council for exclusive access to the village's grazing. The bargain states how many sheep and goats they will bring, when they will come, how long they will stay, and how much they will pay for the franchise. Once the bargain is made, those herders have exclusive claim to the village's grazing, and others can enter only as some leave. Their flocks graze over the stubble by day. By night, when the animals drop most of their manure, they are put on the plots of particular landowners, who pay them an agreed nightly rate per animal. So the herders as a group
  • 59. pay the village a lump sum for access to the commons; and they individually get back part of what they pay through the sale of manure. The second method (used in K, among others) is more complex. Again, a group of herders obtains exclusive access. But instead of a group rent, an auction is held regularly (every four days in K) to decide who will have each flock on his land at night up to the next auction. The auction is arranged by the village council. Half the winning bid (for each flock) is then paid to the herder, and half goes to the village fund. In K, some 9,000 to 13,000 animals commonly enter the village for about six weeks, and the village fund gets about Rs 5,000 in return. Such a large number of animals entering the village when some crops (mainly the irrigated ones) are still standing poses a serious risk of loss for those crop owners. The response is to tighten the regula- tion of the livestock in two ways. One is to stipulate rules for
  • 60. both herder and landowner. These rules are read out at the first auction of the year and may be read out again if infringed. They are worth repeating here because they do not fit easily with the view that Indian villagers cannot, so to speak, get their act together (although they may seem unremarkable compared with the elaborate by-laws of open-field villages in medieval England cited in Ault 1973). For the herder: • He must take the flock to the designated field by 6:30 p.m. and keep it there until 8:00 a.m. • He must not allow the flock to graze standing crops. 2 2 4 Research Observer 2, no. 2 (July 1987) • He must deposit with the council half the money paid to him for
  • 61. the first "turn" (four nights); if he leaves before completing four turns (sixteen nights), he forfeits his deposit to the village fund. (This is to discourage herders from leaving before the farmers have had their fields manured and cleared of stubble.) • He must stay within the village boundary; if the farmer asks him to go to a field outside he must refuse. For the farmer: • He must keep the flock within the village boundary. • If he prefers to pay the fund or the herder in kind rather than cash, he must make the conversion at the rate (in early 1980) of Rs 1.25 per measure of hybrid sorghum or Rs 1.50 of "local" sorghum. • To help the herder guard the flock at night, he must provide two men for each 2,000 head. Hired guards must be paid Rs 3 a night, or the equivalent in grain. (This is to prevent the farmer from
  • 62. sending nonablebodied men, who could be paid less.) Such rules are not self-enforcing. Any one farmer would have an incentive to cheat, by not providing the stipulated number of guards or by bringing the flock to a field outside the village boundary. So joint regulation is carried further by means of village- appoint- ed guards. To pay the guards, it would be possible for the council to set a flat rate—so much per cultivated acre—which each landowner had to pay. But such an arrangement would be vulnerable to free riding: a farmer could delay payment indefinitely, expecting that others would not similarly delay. In most villages this free rider problem is avoided by raising the money for the guards' salaries from a collective source. The chief source is the money received from the sale of the grazing
  • 63. franchise, which is generally enough to pay for a semipermanent team of field guards. The "corporate" irrigated villages tend to have several other sources of revenue for the standing fund, based mostly on the sale of council-sanctioned franchises. In addition to the grazing franchise, a franchise to sell liquor is a valuable source of revenue. By law the franchise is sold in a government-run auction. However, the corporate villages usually send just one person from their village, thus acquiring the franchise at the lowest price. They then auction it within the village which, with competition, produces a higher price. The difference be- tween the two prices goes to the village fund. Or again, one village in the sample has an irrigation tank (a small reservoir). Each year the council stocks it with fingerlings, and later in the year auctions the
  • 64. franchise to catch the fish, the money going to the fund. Some villages auction the right to collect a commission on all their grain sales. Robert Wade 2 2 5 The Management of Irrigation Any irrigation system that experiences water shortages poses an inherent conflict between farmers upstream and those downstream. Those upstream have first access, and their supply is relatively abun- dant; how much they take determines how much the downstreamers will get. Without some rules about access, continual conflicts are likely. The villages in the sample are irrigated from large, government- run
  • 65. canals and grow rice in the first (wet) season. The rice is transplanted in late July or early August and harvested in December and January. By the end of September the heavy rains have normally stopped, so the crop depends on canal water. Common irrigators are then ap- pointed to allocate the scarce and fluctuating supply of canal water over the village's land and also to procure, by various means, more water from the government-run supply (which may include surrepti- tiously blocking the outlets of upstream villages). This arrangement is notable in two respects. First, the common irrigators do not decide how much land will make a claim to the irrigation water; that is left to individual farmers (as are decisions about how many animals to graze). Second, however, once the com- mon irrigators are appointed, they take important decisions out of the hands of individual farmers, in the name of a villagewide
  • 66. authority. The criterion used by the common irrigators is "adequately wet- ted." Each field is entitled to be adequately wetted, but it cannot get more water until the other fields downstream from that outlet (most villages have several outlets) have also been adequately wetted. This criterion is quite different from the open access, first-come- first-served rule that prevails before the common irrigators are appointed. The criterion is also quite different from the approach in northwest India, where canal water is always scarce; there during a fixed period of the week each field is entitled to draw whatever water is flowing in the watercourse, but cannot draw more until the same time the following week. The difference in approach presumably derives from the difference
  • 67. between rice (in Andhra Pradesh) and other crops (in the Northwest). Rice is more adversely affected than other crops if the water available is less than potential evapotranspiration; however, rice does not suffer from excessive irrigation. As a result, one farmer's overgenerous irri- gation of a rice crop can cause drastic yield reductions for others. Therefore, whereas the Northwest's "fixed time per acre" method is self-policing—the next farmer in line knows exactly when his turn should start—the judgment of adequate wetting cannot be left to each irrigator and must be made by people answerable to a villagewide authority. Farmers who steal water—who try to influence how much water 226 Research Observer 2, no. 2 (July 1987)
  • 68. they get once the common irrigators have been appointed—are liable to be fined by the council. During a drought, the fines may be Rs 20 to 50 each time, but the main penalty is the stigma of being dressed- down in front of the council. The common irrigators are paid at harvest time, not from the village fund but by means of a levy—so much per irrigated acre—on each irrigator. The rate is set by the council. Is this not vulnerable to free riding? The short answer is no, because the levy is in kind rather than cash and is made at the harvest—the one time of the year when every farmer has no excuse to delay payment in kind. More impor- tant, common irrigators who are not paid one year can damage the nonpayer the next year. The withdrawal of common irrigator services from one individual's land has graver implications than does the
  • 69. withdrawal of field-guarding services. This article has so far discussed how things are done in the corpo- rate villages, those with all or most of the four corporate institutions. Although most of the detailed information comes from K village, the organization of the four key institutions varies little from village to village, even though they were not imposed from above. Many villages, however, have no corporate organization: no village council, no standing fund, no common irrigators, and no village- appointed guards (though private landowners may hire their own, sometimes forming small groups to do so). In these villages the rule of open access to canal water applies, although informal turn- sharing may develop along some watercourses. And uncoordinated groups of herders may enter a village's land at will, or with the permission
  • 70. of the headman, and will negotiate with individual farmers about where they fold their flocks at night. Why the difference between the corporate and uncorporate villages? The first point is that the corporate irrigated villages are located toward the tail-end of an irrigation distributary (roughly, the bottom one-third of its length; typical distributaries are ten miles long). The second point is that the corporate dry villages tend to be located in areas with black, rather than red, soil. The third point is that, in the semiarid tropics generally, black soil areas tend to be lower down a watershed than red soil areas. So irrigated villages toward the tail-end of a distributary also tend to have a higher proportion of black soils. Black soils are more water-retentive than red soils, allowing a wider
  • 71. range of rainfed crops and a higher yield—and hence a more abun- dant and varied supply of stubble. With unrestrained access, too many animals might come in, damaging the soil. Moreover, the risks of crop loss are higher: with the more varied cropping pattern of black soils, large areas of stubble from the early-harvested crops will become The Ecological Basis of Common Property Rules Robert Wade 227 available when other crops are still standing. This provides the impe-
  • 72. tus to arrange for the fields to be guarded, which can be financed by the herders' willingness to pay for the better grazing on black soil. In theory, the power structure of the village might be such that collective action was impossible because it was not supported by a few key households with land close to the canal. In practice, however, holdings are typically scattered in small parcels, partly because land- owners want to diversify risk. A family with land close to one irriga- tion outlet may have another plot close to the tail-end of a block fed from another outlet. This greatly helps the consensus on the need for rules and joint regulation. Areas of rainfed cultivation higher up a distributory have more red soil, which dries out sooner after the rains stop. They therefore have less stubble, so herders are less interested in grazing there. The
  • 73. higher irrigated areas tend to be under rice in both seasons, but sheep and goat manure is wanted mainly for other crops. So both the demand and supply of animals and grazing is less in the higher villages—and canal water there is more plentiful and reliable. It is in villages lower down a watershed that the potential for conflict is greatest. The evidence of my sample suggests that these lower villages are very likely to have an organized public domain, with rules on the use of water and grazing and the provision of other public goods. How effective are the rules of restrained access in changing the way that resources are used? This question is difficult to answer, because it is hard to find a pair of similar villages, one with corporate institu- tions, one without. All one can say with confidence is that both production and equity are greater where rules and institutions apply
  • 74. than they would have been had the same villages been unorganized. Where individual benefits from joint action are high, joint action is likely to be forthcoming. This is not to say that the temptation for self-interested individuals to go for immediate gain is minor. The need to respond to the free rider problem affects a village's organization. The typical council has developed formidable arrangements for enforcing the rules, precisely to convince each individual that his fellow villagers will probably abide by the rules, so that if he too does so he will not be the sucker (Runge 1984). These expectations are reinforced by the social compo- sition of the council, an elite body with no pretense at representation. Councils have increased their authority with the passage of time: in all these villages, they have been operating for several decades
  • 75. at least. Lessons What of Olson's argument? One of its main weaknesses is a lack of for Theory attention to the size and nature of the collective benefit.1 It concen- trates instead on the size of the selective benefits and costs, those that 2 2 8 Research Observer 2, no. 2 (J"'y 1987) can discriminate between people according to whether or not they help to provide the public good. It simply assumes the net collective benefit to be high, since free riders must by definition be among those who value the public good highly. So the argument is geared to interpret noncooperation as evidence for the free rider hypothesis, rather than for the hypothesis of low collective benefit. In these Indian
  • 76. villages, however, cooperation and noncooperation are explained in terms of high and low collective benefit, as indicated by downstream or upstream location on a water supply channel and by black or red soils. The presence or absence of selective punishments has little bearing on the variation among villages. Another qualification to Olson concerns the source of control and punishment. Olson's key proposition—that examples of collective ac- tion groups can be explained as the response to selective punishments or rewards—differs from the more conventional notion that joint be- havior is related to the presence of an external enforcer of agreements. Olson is not entirely clear on whether the source of selective punish- ment or reward is inside the group or outside. But he can be read to mean that the penalties must be organized from outside the
  • 77. group. This notion is contradicted by my findings and those of many others. There are many examples where villagers have established rules, monitored the conditions of the commons, checked for cheat- ing, and assigned punishment.3 There are also, of course, many more examples where attempts to do so have failed; in the absence of state regulation or private property, the commons has then degenerated. But the successful examples of local rules show that regulation of the commons does not have to be imposed from outside (McKean 1984; Ostrom 1986). Where Olson and other pessimists about collective action are surely right is in the need for coercion to back up agreements. Their empha- sis on the difficulties of voluntary collective action is a useful counter
  • 78. to the simple optimism of those who believe that community develop- ment projects, people's participation, water users' associations, and the like are mainly a matter of teaching people about their real common interests or promoting values that are less individualistic. On the contrary, rules that make people do what they may not imme- diately want to do are a necessary ingredient of managing common resources, so that while free riding tendencies may remain, they need not destroy the organization. The voluntariness of collective action, therefore, has to be consid- ered as a constitutional issue and as a matter of action. Constitution- ally, people can agree on a set of rules of restrained access or financial contributions, their incentive to do so being prospective net collective benefit. In action, compliance with the rules must also be mainly
  • 79. voluntary, not the result of a calculus of evasion and punishment. But Robert Wade 2 2 9 the rules must be backed by a system of punishment, which helps to assure each individual that if he follows the rules he will not be cheated, and which at times of crisis can directly deter violations.4 Lessons for Organiza tional Design If an outside authority wanted to encourage the establishment of some cooperative bodies, how would it choose to design them? One lesson is that, in the South Indian context at least, villagers are likely to follow joint rules and arrangements only to achieve intensely felt
  • 80. needs that could not be met by individual action (Johnston and Clark 1982). These are likely to involve primarily the defense of production (avoidance of crop or animal loss), secondarily the enhancement of income, and last by a long way, education, nutrition, health, and civic consciousness. The opportunities for avoiding losses or boosting in- come by collective action will be taken only if the losses or gains are large. In my irrigated villages, corporate organization to manage com- mon property is found, with barely an exception, only toward the tail-ends of distributaries. The second lesson is that corporate organizations, to be effective, should be based on existing structures of authority. In practice, this means that the council will be dominated by the local elite, which is a disturbing conclusion for democrats and egalitarians. But rules
  • 81. made by the majority of villagers would carry little legitimacy in the eyes of the powerful. More important, the effectiveness of a council depends on its councillors all having a substantial private interest in seeing that it works, and that interest is greater the larger a person's land- holding (provided holdings are in scattered parcels). Moreover, the tendency of the nonelite to cheat can be checked by the sanctions of the village's power structure. Without these wider sanctions, the coun- cil's formal penalties would probably be ineffectual. This point tends to be overlooked in the public choice literature because it assumes a context of free and equal individuals. If the elite runs the council, will it not become another instrument of exploitation? That is not so in these Indian villages, which reflects
  • 82. the third design lesson: the council is concerned only with nonpriva- tizable benefits. It is not involved in supplying inputs other than water. It is not involved in settling disputes unrelated to husbandry or water. It does not try to compensate the owners of animal- damaged crops, for that would create conflict about privatizable value. In K village, the council once tried to intervene in the allocation of a privatizable good (rationed sugar): the conflicts over who got it be- came so strong that the council almost ceased to function. The fourth lesson is that a council should take on less vital func- tions (well repairing, monkey catching, and so on) only when it is very good at the core (income-defending or income-enhancing) activi- 230 Research Observer 2, no. 2 (July 1987)
  • 83. ties. Not all those councils that are organized to do the essentials also do much less-essential work. The fifth lesson is to keep the techniques of calculation and control simple. Some record keeping and accountability are needed, so as to "institutionalize suspicion," in Ronald Dore's phrase (1971). But the accountability procedures are straightforward in these Indian villages. There is an annual general meeting of all farmers to discuss the forth- coming season, ratify the new council, and receive nominations for guards. The records on standing fund income and expenditure are simple and are read out at the general meeting. Meetings of the council are held in the open, and anyone who passes can listen on the fringes. One specific lesson is that, where water users' associations are deliberately fostered, the right unit of organization is usually
  • 84. the whole village. Attempts to form a water users' association around each canal outlet are likely to be futile if such a group of farmers does not already do other things together. The group will simply not contain enough authority. Yet many programs for irrigation improve- ment in India assume that the natural unit of organization is the outlet or some other hydrologically defined unit. More generally, what can be said about the conditions on which successful collective action depends? In the extreme case— many users, unclear boundaries of the common, resources, people scattered over a large area, rules easy to break—degradation of the commons can confidently be expected as demand increases, and privatization or state regulation may be the only options. The likelihood of successful collective action therefore depends on the following:5 • Resources. The smaller and more clearly defined the boundaries of
  • 85. the common resources, the greater the chances of success. • Technology. The higher the costs of exclusion technology (such as fencing), the better the chances of success. • Relation between resources and users Location: The greater the overlap between the location of the common-pool resources and the residence of the users, the greater the chances of success. Users' demands: The greater the demands (up to a limit) and the more vital the resource for survival, the greater the chances of success. Users' knowledge: The more users know about sustainable yields, the greater the chances of success. • Characteristics of users Size: The smaller the number of users, the better the chances of success. However, there is a minimum number below which the
  • 86. tasks able to be performed by such a small group cease to be meaningful. Robert Vfftule 231 Boundaries: The more clearly defined the boundaries of the group, the better the chances of success. Relative power of subgroups: The more powerful are those who benefit from retaining the commons and the weaker are those who favor enclosing private property, the better the chances of success. Existing arrangements for discussion of common problems: The more developed such arrangements are, the greater the chances of success. Extent to which users are bound by mutual obligation: The more concerned people are about their social reputations, the better the chances of success.
  • 87. • Noticeability. The more noticeable is cheating on agreements, the better the chances of success. Noticeability is a function partly of how clearly defined are the resource boundaries, how near they are to users' residences, and how large is the group of users. • Relation between users and the state. The less the state can or wishes to undermine locally based authorities and the less it can enforce private property rights effectively, the better the chances of success. As the list implies, there can be no presumption that collective action will generally work—any more than there can be a presump- tion that private property or state regulation will generally work. My argument is only that (a) the propensity to descend into anarchy or destruction is neither as strong nor as general as mainstream collective action theory implies and (b) that where circumstances look
  • 88. promis- ing for collective action government officials should treat this option as seriously as the other two. The government can help these local systems by providing a legal framework and perhaps technical assistance. The legal framework should enable village organizations to obtain legally enforceable re- cognition of their identity and rights and to call upon the state as an enforcer of last resort (Korten, forthcoming). Obvious though it may sound, few governments in Asia have given much attention to this task, at least with respect to rural (as distinct from modern urban) organizations. If governments did more, their efforts would widen the range of situations in which locally based common property regimes could be expected to work.
  • 89. Abstract When will villagers come together to supply themselves with goods and services that they all need but could not provide for themselves individually? Can locally based collective action be a viable way to manage common property resources? Many writers on collective action and common property are pessimistic about the ability of people who face problems with common property resources to organize sustainable patterns of use for themselves. Some writers favor privatization of the commons as the only viable solution; others, the imposition of state regulation. This article shows, with reference 2 3 2 Research Observer 2, no. 2 (July 1987) to Mancur Olson's "logic of collective action," that the analytical basis for this pessimism is weak for the village-based use of common property resources. There can thus be no general presumption that collective action will fail in the management of
  • 90. common property resources, any more than there can be a general presumption that it will work. The article suggests that the chances of success through collective action depend on the characteristics of the resources, the user group, and group-state relations. This article is based on a forthcoming book, Village Republics: Economic Conditions NotCS for Collective Action in South India, Cambridge University Press. I am grateful to Hans Binswanger, Richard Kimber, Ford Runge, and especially Elinor Ostrom for discussions on various points of the argument. 1. For references, see citations later in text. 2. It is not that Olson says or implies that the size of the collective net benefit is irrelevant; he simply does not give it much attention. 3. For example, McKean (1984) on Japan; Gilles and Jamtgaard (1981) on Peru; Campbell and Godoy (1985) on the Andes; Hitchcock (1980), Peters (1983), and
  • 91. Thomsen (1980) on Africa; and Netting (1978) on Switzerland. See also Runge (1987) and Ostrom (1985b). 4. This argument is in line with some of the early writings in public choice theory, notably Buchanan and Tullock (1962) and Ostrom (1968). Later work in the public choice tradition has tended to focus too much on the issue of financial contributions. I have not discussed here the issue of group size. Olson's celebrated theorem, stated without qualification early in his book, is later restricted to large groups in a taxonomy of small, intermediate, and large. He says little about how to distinguish the three types of groups in practice, but he might argue that the groups under discussion here are intermediate groups and therefore outside the scope of his argument. 5: See also Ostrom (1985b), the starting point of my own formulation.
  • 92. Ault, W. 1973. Open-field Farming in Medieval England: A Study of Village By-laws. London: Allen and Unwin. Blomquist, W., and E. Ostrom. 1985. "Institutional Capacity and the Resolution of a Commons Dilemma." Policy Studies Review 5, no. 2: 383-93. Buchanan, J., and G. Tullock. 1962. The Calculus of Consent. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press. Campbell, Bruce, and R. Godoy. 1985. "Common-field Agriculture: The Andes and Medieval England Compared." Queens University of Belfast, Geography Department. Carruthers, I., and R. Stoner. 1981. Economic Aspects and Policy Issues in Groundwater Development. World Bank Staff Working Paper 496. Washington, D.C. Demsetz, H. 1967. "Toward a Theory of Property Rights." American Economic Review 57: 347-59.
  • 93. Dore, R. 1971. "Modern Cooperatives in Traditional Communities." In P. Worsley, ed. Two Blades of Grass. Manchester: Manchester University Press. Gilles, J. L., and K. Jamtgaard. 1981. "Overgrazing in Pastoral Areas: The Commons Reconsidered." Sociologia Ruralis 21: 129-41. Hardin, G. 1968. "The Tragedy of the Commons." Science 162 (December): 1343-48. Hitchcock, R. K. 1980. "Tradition, Social Justice, and Land Reform in Central Botswana." Journal of African Law 24: 1-34. Johnson, O. 1972. "Economic Analysis, the Legal Framework and Land Tenure Systems." journal of Law and Economics 15: 259-76. References Robert Wade 233
  • 94. Johnston, B., and W. Clark. 1982. "Organization Programs: Institutional Structures and Managerial Procedures." In Redesigning Rural Development: A Strategic Perspective. Baltimore, Md.: Johns Hopkins University Press. Korten, F. 1987. "The Policy Framework for Community Management." In D. Korten, ed. Community Management: Asian Experiences and Perspectives. Hartford, Conn.: Kumarian Press. McCloskey, D. 1975. "The Persistence of English Common Fields." In W. Parker and E. Jones, eds. European Peasants and Their Markets: Essays in Agrarian Economic History. Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press. McKean, M. 1984. "Management of Traditional Common Lands in Japan." Duke University, Department of Political Science. Netting, R. 1978. "Of Men and Meadows: Strategies of Alpine Land Use." Anthropolog-
  • 95. ical Quarterly 45, no. 3: 132-44. North, D., and R. Thomas. 1977. "The First Economic Revolution." Economic History Review 30: 229-41. Olson, M. 1971. The Logic of Collective Action. Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press. Ostrom, E. 1968. "Some Postulated Effects of Learning on Constitutional Behavior." Public Choice 5 (Fall): 87-104. 1985a. "Are Successful Efforts to Manage Common-Pool Resources A Challenge to the Theories of Garrett Hardin and Mancur Olson?" Working Paper W85-31. Indiana University, Workshop in Political Theory and Policy Analysis. . . 1985b. "The Rudiments of a Revised Theory of the Origins, Survival, and Performance of Institutions for Collective Action." Working Paper W85-32. Indiana
  • 96. University, Workshop in Political Theory and Policy Analysis. . . 1986. "Institutional Arrangements for Resolving the Commons Dilemma: Some Contending Approaches." In B. McKay and J. Acheson, eds. Capturing the Com- mons. Tucson: University of Arizona Press. Peters, Pauline. 1983. "Cattlemen, Borehold Syndicates and Privatization in the Kgatleng District of Botswana." Ph.D. dissertation, Boston University. Picardi, A., and W. Siefert. 1976. "A Tragedy of the Commons in the Sahel." Technology Review 78: 42-51. Randall, A.-1.983. "The Problem of Market Failure." Natural Resources Journal 23, no. 1: 131^*8. Runge, C. Ford. 1984. "Institutions and the Free Rider: The Assurance Problem in Collective Action." Journal of Politics 46: 154-81. 1987. "Common Property and Collective Action in Economic
  • 97. Development." World Development. Forthcoming. Thomsen, James T. 1980. "Peasant Perceptions of Problems and Possibilities for Local- Level Management of Trees in Niger and Upper Volta." Paper presented at the African Studies Association Meetings, October 15-18. Wade, Robert. 1985. "Common Property Resource Management in South Indian Villages." Agricultural Research Unit Discussion Paper 35. World Bank, Agriculture and Rural Development Department, Washington, D.C. 1986. "The Management of Common Property Resources: Collective Action as an Alternative to Privatization or State Regulation." Agricultural Research Unit Discussion Paper 54. World Bank, Agriculture and Rural Development Department, Washington, D.C. . . 1987. Village Republics: Economic Conditions for Collective Action in South