SlideShare a Scribd company logo
1 of 31
1
Smartphone Patent Wars: Legal & Policy Issues of Standard Essential Patens in ICT
Industry
by Alex G. Lee1
As represented by “Smartphone Patent Wars,” patents for smartphones became the most
important strategic competition tool among market leaders. Especially, patents for mobile
communication standards, which are the so-called ‘Standard Essential Patents (SEPs),’ became
the center of legal and policy debates regarding their intellectual property rights (IPRs).
The author provides the implications of recent courts’ resolutions regarding FRAND
(Fair, Reasonable And Non Discriminatory) disputes to the ICT (Information and
Communications Technology) industry and provide several alternative options for resolving
FRAND disputes. The author contends that the current concerted resolutions in courts and
regulation agencies can results in adverse effects to the ICT industry. The author also contends
the main drawback of the recent proposals to resolve the disputes surrounding SEPs through the
ex ante FRAND licensing and the ICT industry players’ voluntary collaboration. From the
analysis of ICT industry players’ response to the outcomes of court resolutions, the author
contends a compromising way to provide FRAND Royalty adopting arguments from both sides
of the disputes. The author also contends a practical improvement to the voluntary collaboration
proposals to resolve the disputes surrounding SEPs.
1
Alex Geunho Lee, Ph.D., earned his J.D. from the Suffolk University Law School. He thanks to Professor
Christopher Gibson for directing this thesis paper. He also thanks to Professor Michael L. Rustad, Ms. Hee-Eun
Kim, Mr. Larry M. Goldstein and Professor Stephen Y. Chow for valuable comments.
2
Table of Contents
I. Introduction
II. A Holistic Review of Current Issues in FRAND Disputes
A. Interpretation of FRAND Commitments
B. Determination of FRAND Royalty
C. Antitrust Issue
III. Implications for ICT Industry
A. Response of ICT Industry to the Courts’ Resolutions
B. Potential Adverse Effects of Courts’ Resolutions
C. Alternative Methods to Resolve FRAND Disputes
IV. Recommendations
A. FRAND Royalty and Injunctive Relief
B. Alternative Methods for FRAND Licensing
V. Conclusion
3
I. Introduction
Smartphones, which are the convergence products of computers and mobile
communication devices, are now revolutionizing our life style, business activities, and society as
a whole. Current smartphone boom started when the first iPhone was released on June 29, 2007.
According to a market research by comScore in January of 2013, 129.4 million people in the
United States owned smartphones, which is about 55 percent of mobile subscribes.2
Globally,
total smartphone sales reached $250 billion in 2012.3
The heavy competition among smartphone manufactures for establishing competitive
market position in the newly formed lucrative business has led to recent intensive patent
infringement lawsuits, which are the so-called ‘Smartphone Patent Wars.’ Smartphone Patent
Wars began in 2009 when Nokia sued Apple and Apple countersued Nokia.4
Then, the
Smartphone Patent Wars extended globally involving new players from smartphone
manufactures to makers of smartphone related products such as tablets and entertainment
devices.5
When Apple accused Motorola and Samsung of infringement of its user interface
software and design patents, Motorola and Samsung counter-attacked through new patent
lawsuits utilizing their patents for mobile communication standards, which are the so-called
2
Score Press Releases, U.S. Smartphone Subscriber Market Share,
http://www.comscore.com/Insights/Press_Releases/2013/3/comScore_Reports_January_2013_U.S._Smartphone_Su
bscriber_Market_Share (last visited April 1, 2013).
3
AP News, Smartphone 4Q Sales Rise 36 PCT Led by Samsung, http://bigstory.ap.org/article/smartphone-4q-sales-
rise-36-pct-led-samsung (last visited April 1, 2013).
4
Wikipedia, Smartphone wars, http://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Smartphone_wars (last visited April 1, 2013).
5
Competing smartphone manufactures can be grouped as iOS group represented by Apple, Android group
represented by Google and its subsidiary Motorola, and Windows Mobile group represented by Microsoft by the
operating systems of the smartphones.
4
‘Standard Essential Patents (SEPs).’ SEPs were a natural choice for Motorola and Samsung,
which were incumbents in mobile communication industry and holders of strong mobile patent
portfolios, to counter-attack Apple, which is the computer industry incumbent, and thus, lacks in
SEPs for mobile communications.
SEPs encompass intellectual property rights (IPRs) for the standardized technologies.
Usually, all the essential aspects of standardized technologies are specified in standard
specifications.6
Thus, SEPs can be defined as patents that include one or more claims that are
infringed by the implementation of certain standard specifications. Consequently, Apple’s
standard-compatible products that implement the standard specifications for mobile
communications may infringe SEPs of Motorola and Samsung. Therefore, Motorola and
Samsung sought to demand a sales ban of Apple’s standard-compatible products in addition to
monetary relief. The outcomes, however, were different than expected in the usual SEPs
litigation scenario.7
Standards are often developed and set-up through the standardization process by the
standard setting organizations (SSOs).8
If the adopted standards are covered by some patents
owned by the members that proposed the adopted standards, the members become the patentees
of SEPs. The patentee of SEPs may have market power in the relevant technology market
6
To facilitate interoperability among the industry players, participants in the development of standards establish
specifications for the essential components of the standardized technology. “The standard specifications, however,
do not define all the technical aspects for commercial products implementation.
7
The main advantage of using SEPs is their easy of proof characteristic for infringement analysis. Once a patent in
litigation is proved to be a SEP, it was an assumption that the accused standard-compatible product should infringe
the SEP. Therefore, the infringer reluctantly came to the negotiation table for a licensing of the SEP.
8
In this article, SSO will be used interchangeably with the traditional term SDO (Standard Developing
Organization). During the standardization process, participating members propose their preferred standard
applications to the technical committees of SSOs. Board members of the technical committees, then, review the
proposed standard applications and submit the adopted applications to the technical committees to decide whether to
accept the adopted applications through a voting among the participating members. See, e.g., Wikipedia, Standards
Organization, http://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Standards_organization (last visited October 1, 2013).
5
because the industry may be locked-in to using the standard and the value of SEPs becomes
significantly enhanced. Thus, the patentee can demand and obtain unreasonably high royalty
payments – hold up value - due to very high switching cost to alternative technology the
implementer should pay.9
Thus, the patent hold up occurs when a patentee of SEPs demands
unreasonably higher license fees after the standard is widely adopted than could have been
obtained before the standard was implemented.
To avoid the patent holdup problem, a majority of the SSOs require that the members
participating in the standardization process to agree ex ante to license their SEPs under fair,
reasonable, and nondiscriminatory (FRAND)10
terms ex post to any implementers of the standard.
The members’ agreements to license their SEPs under FRAND terms are usually called FRAND
commitments. In general, FRAND commitments are interpreted as enforceable contractual
obligations between a member and an SSO.11
An implementer of the standard is a third-party
beneficiary of FRAND commitments and therefore entitled to a license of SEPs.12
FRAND
commitments can also be interpreted as encumbrances of SEPs as in servitudes for real
9
See, e.g., Mark A Lemley & Carl Shapiro, Patent Holdup and Royalty Stacking, 85 Tex. L. Rev, 1991, 2007 (2007).
10
In this article, FRAND will be used interchangeably with RAND (reasonable, and nondiscriminatory). In FRAND,
fair means to underlying licensing terms are not un-fair. Reasonable means that the licensing royalty rates should not
be excessively higher than the value of benefits that can be acquired by the license. Non-discriminatory means
licensors treat all licensees in a similar manner in licensing agreements. See, e.g., Wikipedia, Reasonable and non-
discriminatory licensing, http://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Reasonable_and_non-discriminatory_licensing (last visited
October 1, 2013).
11
Mark A. Lemley, Intellectual Property Rights and Standard-Setting Organizations, 90 Cal. L. Rev. 1889, 1909-
1918 (2002).
12
Here, the beneficiary includes both member and nonmember of the SSO. See, e.g., Lemley, supra note 10, at 1915.
6
properties.13
Thus, FRAND commitments create FRAND-encumbered IPRs that run with
SEPs.14
An implementer of the standard holds entitlements of FRAND commitments to SEPs.
Considering all the interest parties surrounding FRAND commitments, the disputes over
SEPs in Smartphone Patent Wars lead to FRAND disputes involving directly concerned parties,
public policy initiated interruptions by regulation agencies, and courts’ interpretations about
FRAND commitments. These disputes take on an increasing importance in the information and
communications technology (ICT) industry.
The main purpose of this article is to understand the implications of recent courts’
resolutions regarding FRAND disputes to the ICT industry and provide several alternative
options for resolving FRAND disputes. I contended that the current concerted resolutions in
courts and regulation agencies can results in adverse effects to the ICT industry. I also
contended the main drawback of the recent proposals to resolve the disputes surrounding SEPs
through the ex ante FRAND licensing and the ICT industry players’ voluntary collaboration.
From the analysis of ICT industry players’ response to the outcomes of court resolutions, I
contended a compromising way to provide FRAND Royalty adopting arguments from both sides
of the disputes. I also contended a practical improvement to the voluntary collaboration
proposals to resolve the disputes surrounding SEPs.
This article is organized as follows. In Section II, I will present a holistic review of
current issues in FRAND disputes. This section includes details about major issues in FRAND
disputes, courts resolutions, and policy measures by regulation agencies: How to interpret
FRAND commitments?; When is a patentee of SEPs entitled to an injunctive relief?; Is an
13
Jay P. Kesan & Carol M. Hayes, FRAND's Forever: Standards, Patent Transfers, and Licensing Commitments
(Illinois Public Law Research Paper No. 13-31, 2013), available at
http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=2226533. p. 88
14
If the SEPs are sold to someone else, FRAND commitments automatically transfer to the new SEPs holder.
7
exclusion order for SEPs in the International Trade Commission (ITC) available?; What is the
appropriate remedial compensations for SEPs?; Can exploitations of SEPs without limitation be
liable for antitrust violation?
Having understood the background of smartphone patent wars surrounding SEPs and
holistic review of current issues in FRAND disputes, I introduce implications of current legal
and policy issues surrounding SEPs for the ICT industry in Section III: Will the ICT industry
players agree to the outcomes of court resolutions?; Is there any possibility that the outcomes of
the current concerted resolutions in courts and regulation agencies affect the ICT industry
players adversely? Are there any better ways to resolve the disputes surrounding SEPs through
the ICT industry players’ voluntary collaboration?
In Section IV, I present a set of recommendations in light of the analysis above: Hybrid
approach to FRAND royalty; Law and economic analysis for injunctive relief; Collaboration
between SSOs and patent offices for ex ante FRAND licensing; and Establishment of
international arbitration agency for FRAND disputes resolution. I conclude this article in
Section V.
II. A Holistic Review of Current Issues in FRAND Disputes
A. Interpretation of FRAND Commitments
FRAND commitments under SSOs’ IPR polices
8
Many SSOs adopt IPR polices to implement their members’ agreement to FRAND
commitments. However, definition of FRAND terms is not specified in SSOs’ IPR polices.15
Thus, what is meant by fair, reasonable, and nondiscriminatory is left to the interpretation of
parties who are involved in the FRAND commitments. Furthermore, SSOs’ IPR polices
normally do not specify the conditions for contractual agreement under the FRAND
commitments to form binding obligations to the parties. The reason behind the fact that SSOs’
IPR polices normally do not specify the conditions for contractual agreement under the FRAND
commitments can be understand as an effort to avoid risk of any antitrust liabilities.16
SSOs
often involve agreements among horizontal competitors. Thus, specifying the FRAND
commitments can be considered as raising traditional antitrust concerns such as price fixing,
exclusive dealing, etc.17
Consequently, the absence of clear definitions about FRAND terms for
binding obligations in SSOs’ IPR polices is the main causes of FRAND disputes surrounding
SEPs.18
15
See, e.g., Rudi Bekkers & Andrew Updegrove, A study of IPR policies and practices of a representative group of
Standards Setting Organizations worldwide, project report on Intellectual Property Management in standard setting
processes, STEP, 2012, http://home.tm.tue.nl/rbekkers/nas/Bekkers_Updegrove_NAS2012_main_report.pdf (last
visited June 1, 2013).The report exampled twelve representative SSOs such as
International Organization for Standardization (ISO), International Electrotechnical Commission (IEC),
International Telecommunication Union (ITU), Institute of Electrical and Electronics Engineers (IEEE), European
Telecommunications Standards Institute (ETSI), American National Standards Institute (ANSI), Internet
Engineering Task Force (IETF), Organization for the Advancement of Structured Information Standards (OASIS),
VMEBus International Trade Association (VITA). World Wide Web Consortium (W3C), High Definition
Multimedia Interface (HDMI) Forum, and Nearfield Communications (NFC) Forum. Among the 8 SSOs that
adopted FRAND commitments, none of the IPR policies specified the definition of the FRAND terms.
16
Anne Layne-Farrar, A. Jorge Padilla & Richard Schmalensee, Pricing Patents for Licensing in Standard-Setting
Organizations: Making Sense of FRAND Commitments, 74 Antitrust L.J. 671, 678-79 (2007).
17
U.S.DEPARTMENT OF JUSTICE & FEDERAL TRADE COMMISSION, ANTITRUST GUIDELINES FOR
THE LICENSING OF INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY, 1995, available at
http://www.usdoj.gov/atr/public/guidelines/0558.pdf. (last visited Feb. 1, 2013).
18
See, e.g., Kai-Uwe Kühn, Fiona Scott Morton & Howard Shelanski, Standard Setting Organizations Can Help
Solve the Standard Essential Patents Licensing Problem (CPI ANTITRUST CHRON. March special issue, 2013),
available at https://www.competitionpolicyinternational.com/assets/Free/ScottMortonetalMar-13Special.pdf. For
example, if a patentee of SEPs offers a royalty for the licensing agreement to a potential licensee to comply with
9
Courts’ interpretation of the FRAND commitments
In Microsoft, Co. v. Motorola, Inc.19
, the court interpreted FRAND commitments such
that the patentee should grant the implementer a license to its SEPs under FRAND terms. The
Microsoft court ruled that the implementer was not required to negotiate for FRAND terms prior
to filing a breach of contract lawsuit. The court reasoned that, as a third-party beneficiary for
FRAND commitment between a patentee of SEPs and a SSO, Microsoft had an enforceable legal
right to a FRAND license from the patentee prior to a licensing agreement. Thus, the ruling
means that implementer’s offer and negotiation for a patent license were not conditions
precedent for the patentee to obligate to FRAND commitments. Consequently, if the
implementer believes that the patentee’s offer for the license does not meet FRAND terms, it can
bring a lawsuit for breach of FRAND commitments and dispute resolution.
On the other hand, in Orange-Book- Standard20
, the German Federal Supreme Court
(BGH) ruled that the implementer was required to make an unconditional and reasonable offer to
license on FRAND terms prior to patent infringement. The Orange-Book- Standard case
involved SEPs for compact disk standard which was known as the Orange Book. As a defense
for the patent infringement, the defendant in Orange-Book- Standard argued that the plaintiff’s
enforcement of its SEPs violated EU’s antitrust law because the plaint abused its dominant
FRAND commitment and the licensee disagree with the royalty and refuse to proceed the licensing negotiation, the
only way to resolve the dispute is to file a law suit for court’s decision about setting a reasonable royalty.
19
Microsoft, Co. v. Motorola, Inc., No. 2:10-cv-01823-JLR (W.D. WA 2012), Dkt. No. 465 at 12-17. (This lawsuit
involves two SSOs’ SEPs – SEPs for IEEE’s 802.11 Wireless LAN standard and ITU’s H.264 video coding
standard. To comply with IEEE’s IPR policy, Motorola submitted a Letters of Assurance promising that it will grant
a license under reasonable rates, terms, and conditions in a non-discriminatory basis to an unrestricted number of
implementers. To comply with ITU’s IPR policy, Motorola also submitted a Patent Statement and Licensing
Declaration declaring that it will grant a license under reasonable terms and conditions in a non-discriminatory basis
to an unrestricted number of implementers).
20
Orange-Book-Standard, Bundesgerichtshof (BGH), May 6, 2009, KZR 39/06.
10
position in the market. The BGH in Orange-Book- Standard, however, ruled that making an
unconditional offer to license on FRAND was the precondition for the defendant to asset the
anti-competitive defense. Furthermore, the BGH in Orange-Book- Standard also rule that the
patentee of SEPs did not need to accept the offer if it believed that the implementer’s offer was
not reasonable and unconditional. Consequently, the implementer has burden to prove that the
patentee refuses the license notwithstanding the offer was unconditional and reasonable within
the meaning of FRAND terms.
The above mentioned two cases show a clear difference in interpretation of the FRAND
commitments. The Microsoft court interprets that patents of SEPs should offer a reasonable
royalty to the implementer and if the implementer believes that the patentee’s offered royalty for
the license does not meet FRAND terms, it can bring a lawsuit for breach of FRAND
commitments. On the other hand, the Orange-Book- Standard court interprets that the
implementer should offer a reasonable royalty to the patents of SEPs and if the patents of SEPs
believes that the implementer’s offered royalty for the license does not meet FRAND terms, it
can bring a lawsuit for patent infringement. Even if both cases provided different conditions for
FRAND commitment, they indicated the importance of determination of FRAND terms in
resolving FRAND dispute. Especially, a court should provide the reasonable royalty for
licensing agreements under FRAND terms - FRAND royalty. FRAND royalty will be discussed
in detail later of this section.
Availability of injunctive relief for SEPs
11
In Apple, Inc. v. Motorola, Inc.,21
the court interpreted FRAND commitments such that
the patentee “implicitly acknowledged that a royalty is an adequate compensation for a patent
license.” Thus the patentee of SEPs is not entitled to an injunctive relief because “the
inadequacy of monetary relief22
” is required for the entitlement of the injunctive relief and
FRAND royalty would provide the adequate remedy.23
In Microsoft, Co., v. Motorola, Inc.,24
the
court also ruled that a FRAND royalty provides an adequate compensation because a patentee
“has always been required to grant a license” to an implementer at FRAND royalty for its SEPs
and the patentee has not been irreparably harmed.
On the other hand, in Orange-Book- Standard,25
the BGH ruled that a patentee of SEPs is
entitled to injunctive relief. The court interpretation is such that the implementer was required to
make an unconditional offer to license on FRAND terms prior to patent infringement. The court
reasoned that the infringement of SEPs itself shows the implementer’s unwillingness to make an
unconditional offer to license on FRAND terms. Therefore, an injunctive relief is available for
infringed SEPs. However, the court also held that an injunctive relief is not available for
infringed SEPs “if the patentee discriminates or inequitably obstructs” to an implementer’s
unconditional offer to license on FRAND terms and conditions.
21
Apple, Inc. v. Motorola, Inc., No. 1:11-cv-08540 (N.D. Ill. 2012), Dkt. No. 1038 at 18-19. This case involves
SEPs for 3G mobile communications (UMTS) standardized by ETSI.
22
This is one of four factors that should be considered in granting injunctive relief for patent infringement in eBay,
Inc. v. MercExchange, L.L.C., 547 U.S. 388 (2006). The other three factors are 1. The patentee has suffered an
irreparable injury; 2. A remedy in equity is warranted considering the balance of hardships between the patentee and
infringer; 3. The public interest would not be disserved by an injunctive relief.
23
Id. at 21.
24
Microsoft, Co., v. Motorola, Inc., No. 2:10-cv-01823-JLR (W.D. WA 2012), Dkt. No. 607 at 12-15.
25
Orange-Book-Standard, Bundesgerichtshof (BGH), May 6, 2009, KZR 39/06.
12
Availability of exclusion order for SEPs in ITC
In Motorola Mobility, Inc. v. Apple Inc.,26
the Administrative Law Judge ruled that
FRAND commitments do not preclude an exclusion order for SEPs in ITC (International Trade
Commission). The ITC reasoned that its investigations to determine whether to issue an
exclusion order banning importation of infringing product for violations of section 337 of the
Tariff Act of 1930 (19 U.S.C. § 1337) have a wider scope than investigations in courts because
its interests include public interest in addition to private interest.
In Spansion, Inc. v. ITC,27
the court hold that the ITC is not required to apply the
traditional four-factor test of the Supreme Court’s eBay decision for injunctive relief used by
federal district courts. The court reasoned that legislative history of the amendments to Section
337 indicates that Congress intended injunctive relief to be the normal remedy for a Section 337
violation.28
In response to the ITC’s ruling of availability of exclusion order for SEPs two US
government agencies- Department of Justice (DOJ) and Patent & Trademark Office (PTO) -
jointly announced that in some instances the remedy of an exclusion order may be inconsistent
with the public interest.29
The agencies insisted that SPEs cannot be used to block sales or
imports of infringing products in cases where the patentee tries to exploit the SEPs’ market
26
Motorola Mobility, Inc. v. Apple Inc., In the Matter of Certain Wireless Communication Devices, Portable Music
and Data Processing Devices, Computers and Components Thereof, ITC Inv. No. 337-TA-745.
27
Spansion, Inc. v. ITC, 629 F.3d 1331 (Fed. Cir. 2010).
28
In Tariff Act of 1930, Congress eliminated the monetary remedy of §316 of the Tariff Act of 1922. This
represents a legislative determination that an injunction is the only available remedy for violations of Section 337.
Furthermore, Congress amended Section 337 to remove the requirement of proof of harm to domestic industry in
1988. This represents a legislative determination that it is unnecessary to show irreparable harm to the patentee.
29
U.S.DEPARTMENT OF JUSTICE & U.S. PATENT & TRADEMARK OFFIC, Policy Statement on Remedies
for Standards-Essential Patents , 2013, http:// www.justice.gov/atr/public/guidelines/290994.pdf (last visited Feb. 1,
2013).
13
power through exclusion order for pressuring an implementer to accept unreasonably high
royalty against its FREND commitments.30
The agencies reasoned that such activity and
resulting exclusion order might be anti-competitive, and thus, harm consumers. The agencies
also mentioned that, in cases in which the implementer acts beyond the scope of FRAND
commitments, such as refusing to license on FRAND terms and conditions, an exclusion order
may still be appropriate.31
In response to the ITC’s ruling of availability of exclusion order for Samsung’s SEP of
3G mobile communications,32
the USTR (U.S. Trade Representative) vetoed against the ITC’s
ruling.33
The USTR exercised its latest veto of disapproving the ITC’s ruling 26 years ago. The
USTR reasoned that exploitation of SEPs can effect on competitive conditions in the US
economy and the US consumers adversely.
B. Determination of FRAND Royalty
Appropriate remedial compensation for SEPs
Another issue in FRAND disputes is the appropriate remedial compensation for SEPs. In
Apple, Inc. v. Motorola, Inc.,34
the court ruled that a FRAND royalty should not reflect the ex
post hold up value that SEPs acquired after a standardized technology was adopted widely in the
30
Id. at 6.
31
Id. at 7.
32
Samsung, Inc. v. Apple Inc., Certain Electronic Devices, Including Wireless Communication Devices, Portable
Music and Data Processing Devices, and Tablet Computers, ITC Inv. No. 337-TA-794.
33
USTR representative Michael Froman’s letter to the ITC,
http://www.ustr.gov/sites/default/files/08032013%20Letter_1.PDF (last visited Aug. 20, 2013).
34
Apple, Inc. v. Motorola, Inc., No. 1:11-cv-08540 (N.D. Ill. 2012), Dkt. No. 1038 at 18.
14
relevant technology market. Thus, the FRAND royalty can be a measure of value the
implementer can obtain by adopting the standardized technology over available alternatives at
the time the standard was specified. In other words, FRAND royalty can be the maximum
royalty amount that a licensee would be willing to pay in return for the incremental profit
produced by implementing the patented standardized technology over the alternatives.35
Therefore, hypothetical negotiation framework to determine FRAND royalty subject to the
incremental value over alternatives at the time the standard was specified can be applied.
Opponents of the above court’s reasoning for FRAND royalty, however, argued that a
FRAND royalty should be determined as a reasonable royalty based on a hypothetical
negotiation at the time of infringement36
because the damages adequate to compensate would be
damages that place the patentee in the position it would have been but for the infringement.37
Opponents also argued that the FRAND royalty can be measured from a comparable licensing
price in the relevant licensing marketplace. On the other hand, proponents of the above court’s
reasoning for FRAND royalty, however, argued that market value for FRAND royalty could not
be used as providing the reliable FRAND royalty levels unless the comparable licensing royalty
has not been affected by enhanced market power of SEPs.38
FRAND royalty base and rate
35
Lance E. Gunderson, Stephen E. Dell & Scott W. Cragun, The Analytic Approach as a Technique to Determine a
Reasonable Royalty, in ECONOMIC DAMAGES IN INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY: A HANDS-ONGUIDE TO
LITIGATION 181, 182 (Daniel Slottje ed., 2006).
36
See, e.g., Motorola’s argument in Apple, Inc. v. Motorola, Inc., Case: 12-1548 (Fed. Cir. 2012), Dkt. No. 131 at
19.
37
Brooktree Corp. v. Advanced Micro-Devices, Inc., 977 F.2d 1555, 1579 (Fed. Cir. 1992).
38
Anne Layne-Farrar, A. Jorge Padilla & Richard Schmalensee., supra note 15.
15
Two important questions that the disputes about the appropriate remedial compensations
for SEPs typically leave open are FRAND royalty base and rate. Courts may use a royalty base
equal to the entire market value of an infringing product if “the patented feature is the basis for
consumer demand” for the entire product.39
If the patented feature is not the basis for consumer
demand for the entire product, the royalty base should reflect only the contribution of the
patented feature to consumer demand.40
Thus, if a product consists of many components, the
royalty base can be the market value of the relevant component to consumer demand created by
the patented feature.41
In LaserDynamics, Inc. v. Quanta Computer, Inc.,42
the court ruled that the royalty base
can be the smallest saleable component that embodies the patented feature. By this reasoning,
the FRAND royalty base may be the smallest saleable component that embodies the relevant
SEPs. After the FRAND royalty base was determined, a royalty rate for a specific SEP can be
calculated by taking account of the economic contribution of the specific SEP to the smallest
saleable component that is used in determination of the FRAND royalty base. Additionally, to
evaluate whether a license meets FRAND requirement, a court must also ensure that the royalty
rate reflects the total royalty burden on that component to avoid royalty stacking problem.43
39
Marine Polymer Techs., Inc. v. HemCon, Inc., 672 F.3d 1350, 1360 (Fed. Cir. 2012) (en banc).
40
UNILOC USA, INC. v. MICROSOFT CORP., 632 F.3d 1292, 1318–19 (Fed. Cir. 2011). (When a standard is
incorporated into only one component of a multi-component product, royalties based on the value of the entire
product tend to compensate SEP holders for numerous technologies and features beyond those covered by their
patents, thereby overcompensating them and leading to royalty stacking (the overall cumulative royalty costs for a
given standard in excess of the total product cost))
41
This situation is especially prevalent in the ICT industry.
42
LaserDynamics, Inc. v. Quanta Computer, Inc., 694 F.3d 51, 68 (Fed. Cir. 2012).
43
Even if the royalty rate for individual SEP is low, total royalty rates can be excessively large if the implementer
should have licenses multiple SEPs from different patentees. See, e.g., Lemley, M. A., & Shapiro, C., supra note 8.
"Royalty stacking refers to situations in which a single product potentially infringes on many patents, and thus may
bear multiple royalty burdens. The term 'royalty stacking' reflects the fact that, from the perspective of the firm
16
Guidelines for FRAND royalty determination
In Microsoft Co., v. Motorola, Inc.,44
the court provided basic guidelines for assessing
FRAND royalty. The Microsoft court devised the guidelines based on the Georgia-
Pacific analysis of the reasonable royalty45
modified to take into account SSOs’ primary goals
for requiring FRAND commitments. The court provided five primary goals for adopting
FRAND commitments: 1. Promotion of widespread adoption of SSOs’ standards; 2. Avoidance
of patent hold-up; 3. Avoidance of royalty stacking; 4. Creation of valuable standards; 5.
Exclusion of hold-up value in the reasonable royalty. The court, then, modified the Georgia-
Pacific factors to account for the five primary goals for requiring FRAND commitments. The
key modifications to the Georgia-Pacific factors that the court utilizes in its procedures for
FRAND royalty determination are as follows.
making the product in question, all of the different claims for royalties must be added or 'stacked' together to
determine the total royalty burden borne by the product if the firm is to sell that product free of patent litigation."
44
Microsoft Co., v. Motorola, Inc., No. 2:10-cv-01823-JLR (W.D. WA 2013), Dkt. No. 681 at 25-41.
45
Georgia-Pacific Corp. v. U.S. Plywood Corp., 318 F. Supp. 1116, 1120 (S.D.N.Y. 1970). (Fifteen factors for
determining reasonable royalty are as follows. 1. Royalties patentee receives for licensing the patent in suit; 2. Rates
licensee pays for use of other comparable to the patent in suit; 3. Nature and scope of license in terms of exclusivity
and territory / customer restrictions; 4. Licensor’s established policy and marketing program to maintain patent
monopoly by not licensing others to use the invention; 5. Commercial relationship between licensor and licensee,
such as whether they are competitors or inventor and promoter; 6. Effect of selling the patented specialty in
promoting sales of other products of the licensee; the existing value of the invention to the licensor as a generator of
sales of his non-patented items; and the extent of such derivative or convoyed sales; 7. Duration of patent and term
of license; 8. Established profitability of the products made under the patent, its commercial success and its current
popularity; 9. Utility and advantages of patent property over old modes and devices ; 10. The nature of the patented
invention; the character of the commercial embodiment of it as owned and produced by the licensor; and the benefit
of those who have used the invention; 11. The extent to which the infringer has made use of the invention and the
value of such use; 12. The portion of profit or selling price customarily allowed for the use of the invention; 13. The
portion of realizable profit attributable to the invention as distinguished from non-patented elements, significant
features / improvements added by the infringer, the manufacturing process or business risks; 14. Opinion testimony
of qualified experts; 15. Outcome from hypothetical arm’s length negotiation at the time of infringement began)
17
First, the court modified the term ‘an established royalty’ in the Georgia-Pacific factor 1
as a royalty established through negotiation under FRAND commitments. By this
modification, the court could consider a royalty in a patent pool for the specific SEPs at
issue or comparable licensing transactions as a candidate for the royalty established
through negotiation under FRAND commitments.
Next, the court tried to capture only the ex ante value based on any contribution of the
patented technology to the standard with respect to the Georgia-Pacific factors 6 and 8.
Here, the ex ante value is an economic value of patented technology excluding value
added by being included in the standard. Thus, the ex ante value is comply to the
FRAND commitments because it the economic value of patented technology itself
without involvement of hold-up value.46
Then, the court evaluated FRAND royalty for the value of a SEP determined through the
hypothetical negotiation on the contribution to the standard itself and to the
implementer’s products with respect to the Georgia-Pacific factors 10 and 11.47
C. Antitrust Issue
46
Microsoft Co., v. Motorola, Inc., No. 2:10-cv-01823-JLR (W.D. WA 2013), Dkt. No. 681 at 39.
47
See, e.g., In re INNOV A TIO IP VENTURES, LLC, No. 1:11-cv-09308 (N.D. Ill. 2013), Dkt. No. 975 at 84-86.
(The court applied the Microsoft court’s guidelines to calculate FRAND royalty of WiFi SEPs. The court calculated
the royalty cap using the average profit margin of the WiFi chips that cover all the implemented features of the WiFi
standard in the infringing products. Then, the court calculated FRAND royalty by multiplying the average profit
margin to the contribution of patentee’s SEPs to the profit and pro rata share of patentee’s SEPs to the total number
of WiFi SEPs providing similar contribution to the profit.)
18
The final issue in FRAND disputes is whether the exploitations of SEPs without any
limitation can be liable for antitrust violation. Generally, it is not presumed that holding a patent
means its owners have market power in the context of antitrust violation analysis.48
However, a
patentee of SEPs may have market power in the relevant technology market because the industry
may be locked-in to using the standard and all products must be compatible with the standard.
Thus, if the patentee of SEPs exploits SEPs for excluding competitors in the revenant market, the
exploitation may be considered as abuse of market power created by the standard, with a specific
intent to maintain or strengthen its monopolistic market power.49
In Rambus, Inc. v. Fed. Trade Comm’n,50
the court ruled that Rambus did not violate
Section 2 of Sherman Act as claimed by Federal Trade Commission (FTC) that Rambus’s failure
to disclose SEPs during the standardization process was exclusionary and anticompetitive
conduct. The court reasoned that Rambus’s failure to disclose SEPs in breach of FRAND
commitments did not have an anticompetitive effect. Thus, the mere breach of FRAND
commitments is not enough to show anticompetitive behavior of a patentee of SEPs.51
On the other hand, the European Commission, which is the European Union's
competition authority, announced that the patentee of SEPs in breaching of FRAND
commitments could potentially be subject to proceedings under Article 102 TFEU.52
The
48
35 U.S.C. Section 271(d); Illinois Tool Works Inc. v. Independent Ink, Inc., 547 U.S. 28 (2006).
49
The patentee of SEPs can be liable for violation of section 2 of Sherman Act.
50
Rambus, Inc. v. Fed. Trade Comm’n, 522 F.3d 456 (D.C. Cir. 2008).
51
In Vizio, Inc. v. Funai Elec. Co. Ltd., 2010 WL 7762624 (C.D. Cal. 2010), the court reasoned that more
aggressive anticompetitive activity than mere attempt to harm competition is required to prove antitrust liability.
52
TEUF (Treaty on the Functioning of the European Union) Article 102 prohibits any abuse of dominant market
position.
19
European Commission issued a statement of objections to Samsung’s exploitation of its SEPs in
bringing a patent lawsuit against Apple for breach of FRAND commitments.53
III. Implications for ICT Industry
Having understood the current issues in FRAND disputes and courts’ decisions, I turn my
attention now to the implications of current legal and policy issues surrounding SEPs for the ICT
industry. I first discuss ICT industry players’ response to the outcomes of court resolutions. I
then discuss any potential adverse effects of the outcomes of the current concerted resolutions in
courts and regulation agencies to the ICT industry. Finally, I discuss the recent proposals to
resolve the disputes surrounding SEPs through the ICT industry players’ voluntary collaboration.
A. Response of ICT Industry to the Courts’ Resolutions
Will the ICT industry players agree to the outcomes of courts resolution that injunctive relief is
not available for SEPs?
In response to the court ruling that patentees of SEPs are not entitled to an injunctive
relief,54
Motorola agued in its responsive brief55
that the district court violated Supreme Court
53
European Commission Press Releases, http://europa.eu/rapid/press-release_IP-12-1448_en.htm (last visited April
1, 2013): “Samsung's seeking of injunctions against Apple in various EU Member States on the basis of its mobile
phone SEPs amounts to an abuse of a dominant position prohibited by EU antitrust rules. While recourse to
injunctions is a possible remedy for patent infringements, such conduct may be abusive where SEPs are concerned
and the potential licensee is willing to negotiate a license on FRAND terms. The sending of a Statement of
Objections does not prejudge the final outcome of the investigation.”
54
Apple, Inc. v. Motorola, Inc., No. 1:11-cv-08540 (N.D. Ill.).
55
Apple, Inc. v. Motorola, Inc., No. 12-8540 (Fed. Cir. 2013), Dkt. No. 131 at 56-74.
20
precedent in eBay56
avoiding the negative consequences of courts’ rulings57
and violating the
principle of equity for granting injunction as specified in Patent Act58
by creating a bright-line
categorical rule prohibiting injunctive relief for patentees of SEPs under all circumstances.
Nokia also expressed its concern about categorical rule prohibiting injunctive relief. Nokia
insisted that courts should consider the appropriateness of relief on a case-by-case basis.59
Motorola and Nokia cited the joint statement of DOJ and PTO as a their reasoning for case-by-
case approach:60
Even if the agencies insisted that SEPs cannot be used to block sales of
infringing products in cases that the patentee tries to exploit the SEPs’ market power through
injunction, if the implementer is acting beyond the scope of FRAND commitments such as
refusing to license on FRAND terms, however, an injunction may still be appropriate.61
BlackBerry also expressed its position against the categorical rule banning injunctions because
the categorical rule can ruin a balanced approach between providing exclusive right for
contributing innovation and fair competition in the marketplace.62
On the other hand, Intel argued that allowing injunction for SEPs could open a door for a
patentee of SEPs to exploit SEPs for unreasonable compensation that would distort fair
56
eBay Inc. v. MercExchange, LLC, 547 U.S. 388 (2006).
57
An absolute bar on injunctive relief regarding SEPs would foreclose patent holders’ right for fair compensation
and increase patent litigation.
58
35 U.S.C. §283. “The several courts having jurisdiction of cases under this title may grant injunctions in
accordance with the principles of equity to prevent the violation of any right secured by patent, on such terms as the
court deems reasonable.”
59
Nokia’s amicus briefs with the Federal Circuit: Apple, Inc. v. Motorola, Inc., No. 12-8540 (Fed. Cir. 2013), Dkt.
No. 53-1.
60
DOJ & PTO report, supra. note 28.
61
Id. at 7. This means that SEP implementers seeking a license must also respect FRAND obligations, although
FRAND commitments bind SEP holders only.
62
BlackBerry’s amicus briefs with the Federal Circuit: Apple, Inc. v. Motorola, Inc., No. 12-8540 (Fed. Cir. 2013),
Dkt. No. 154.
21
competition and harm consumers.63
Considering a wide spread use of standard-compatible
products, granting injunction for SEPs could create risky precedent against the equitable
principal of eBay. Microsoft also expressed its position supporting courts’ decision for banning
injunctive relief with respect to SEPs.64
Will the ICT industry players agree to the courts’ determination of FRAND Royalty?
Qualcomm expressed its serious concerns about courts’ ruling to diminish the value of
SEPs in its comments to FTC.65
Qualcomm insisted that there is nothing wrong with the
licensing practice of using the price of the entire end product as the appropriate royalty base,
because licensing at the end user device level has been an industry custom in the
telecommunications sector. By the telecommunications industry custom, Qualcomm explained
that patentees of SEPs usually did not enforce licensing obligation to component manufactures.
Therefore, FRAND royalty base cannot be the smallest saleable component that embodies the
relevant SEPs.
Additionally, Qualcomm reasoned that the contribution of the patented feature to
consumer demand should not be limited to components of devices because extended consumers’
benefits are coming from the services provided by the network connecting devices.66
Therefore,
63
Intel’s amicus briefs with the Federal Circuit: Apple, Inc. v. Motorola, Inc., No. 12-8540 (Fed. Cir. 2013) Dkt. No.
137.
64
Microsoft’s amicus briefs with the Federal Circuit: Apple, Inc. v. Motorola, Inc., No. 12-8540 (Fed. Cir. 2013),
Dkt. No. 144.
65
Comments of Qualcomm, FTC Standards Workshop, Project No. P11-1204, June 13, 2011, http://
ftc.gov/os/comments/motorolagoogle/563708-00022-85574.pdf (last visited Feb. 1, 2013).
66
According to MIT Technology Review, Smartphones Are Eating the World, March 15, 2013,
http://www.technologyreview.com/photoessay/511791/smartphones-are-eating-the-world/ (last visited Feb. 1, 2013),
mobile operators’ service market was $1.2 trillion and mobile phone (including smartphone) market was $269
billion globally in 2012. In fact, mobile network operators commonly subsidize mobile phone prices, and thus,
consumers actually do not pay the full cost of the phones. Hence, even to base licensing royalties on the cost to the
22
the smallest saleable component that embodies the relevant SEPs is actually the device itself in
the telecommunications sector. Furthermore, developing standard technology in mobile
telecommunications is a high-risk business. Thus, without strong patent protection and return for
R&D, there will be no encouragement for further investment in telecommunications standards.
Consequently, artificially diminished royalties on mobile telecommunications standard-
compatible products will impede innovation, and thus, harm to the industry and consumers
ultimately.67
On the other hand, Cisco, HP, and several other IT companies argued that the use
of the entire market value as a royalty base should not be used unless all of the profit of the
infringing product is attributed to the features of SEPs.68
Thus, the value of SEPs should be
determined by apportion to the contribution actually the patented features made to the accused
product. They also insisted that patentees bear the burden of proof for the value of SEPs.
B. Potential Adverse Effects of Courts’ Resolutions
Traditionally, most of patentees of SEPs do not enforce their SEPs unless a large portion
of their revenue is derived from the licensing of SEPs,69
or unless the patentees are accused of
consumers of the phone is incorrect, since the phone prices are maintained at an artificially low level by the network
operators.
67
Qualcomm also expressed its concern about reverse hold up such that an infringer refuses to negotiate in good
faith for a FRAND license.
68
Cisco et al.’s amicus briefs with the Federal Circuit: Apple, Inc. v. Motorola, Inc., No. 12-8540 (Fed. Cir. 2013),
Dkt. No. 93.
69
Qualcomm’s licensing revenue reached $1.6 billion in 2012.
23
patent infringement by competitors.70
As the courts resolution for FRAND commitments
seriously limit the exploitation of SEPs, patentees of SEPs may seek other ways to exploit SEPs.
One possibility is the adoption of “patent privateering.”
Patent privateering is a kind of trolling practice by which holders of SEPs assign patent
trolls to engage in exploiting their IPRs encumbered by FRAND commitments.71
This kind of
outsourcing practice of patent enforcement to patent trolls can adversely affect the ICT industry
and consumers. First, patent privateering can increase patent lawsuits significantly because
patent trolls do not make products or services, and thus, they do not need to worry about counter
lawsuits. Second, patent privateering can harm consumers directly because patent trolls
willingly sue consumers instead of manufactures or service provides.72
Another possibility is the increasing activity of developing SEPs without participating in
SSOs, and thus, without obligations to FRAND commitments. FRAND commitments bind a
patentee who participates in a SSO and agrees to IPR policies of the SSO. If a patentee develops
SEPs without participating in a SSO, however, the patentee does not have the contractual
obligations to FRAND commitments.
Sometimes, developing SEPs without participating in a SSO is possible because some of
key aspects of the technologies adopted during the standardization can already be developed by a
third party who is not the participating member of the SSO. Thus, if the third party filed a patent
70
A common outcome of the counter-attack is a cross-licensing between the two parties in the dispute.
71
See, e.g., Tom Ewing, Indirect Exploitation of Intellectual Property Rights By Corporations and Investors: IP
Privateering and Modern Letters of Marque and Reprisal, 4 HASTINGS SCI. TECH. L.J. 1 (2012).
72
Consumers who simply use an infringing product also infringe the patent: 35 U.S.C. §271. In their article Patent
Assertion Entities and Antitrust: Operating Company Patent Transfer (The Antitrust Source April 2013), available
at http://www.ropesgray.com/~/media/Files/articles/2013/04/Antitrust-Attacks-on-Patent-Assertion-Entities.pdf,
Mark S. Popofsky and Michael D. Laufert provides r several ways to challenge the patent privateering exploiting
current antitrust liabilities.
24
covering the technologies adopted as the standard, he or she can further develop it though patent
prosecution process to be a SEP. In an actual case, when Adaptix, a subsidiary of a patent troll
Acacia Research, sued Ericsson at the ITC for infringement of its 4G LTE SEP,73
Adaptix
claimed that it has no obligations to FRAND commitments because it did not participate in
ETSI’s LTE standardization procedures.
C. Alternative Methods to Resolve FRAND Disputes
Ex Ante FRAND licensing
To provide a forum for discussion among the different stakeholders regarding FRAND
disputes, the ITU organized a one-day workshop74
and a follow-up series of meetings.75
The
main purpose of the workshop and meetings was to provide a guide to resolve FRAND disputes
at the SSO level by adapting IPR policies of SSOs to the changing needs of the ICT industry.
Among several ideas exchanged at the meetings, the workshop introduced one interesting
proposal that may resolve FRAND disputes before the standards are fully deployed. The
approach to resolve FRAND disputes ex ante is named as a pseudo-pool approach to FRAND
licensing.76
The basic concept of the pseudo-pool approach to FRAND licensing is to adopt the
licensing scheme of traditional patent pools under the administration of SSOs. Thus, under the
pseudo-pool approach, the patentees and potential implementers set the reasonable royalty upon
73
Adaptix, Inc. v. Ericsson, Inc., Certain Wireless Communications Base Stations and Components Thereof, ITC
Inv. No. 337-TA-871.
74
ITU Patent Roundtable, http://www.itu.int/en/ITU-T/Workshops-and-Seminars/patent/Pages/default.aspx.
75
TSB Director's Ad Hoc Group, http://www.itu.int/en/ITU-T/ipr/Pages/adhoc.aspx.
76
Jorge Contreras, Fixing FRAND: A Pseudo-Pool Approach to Standards-Based Patent Licensing (Antitrust Law
Journal, Fall 2013, Forthcoming) available at http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=2232515.
25
final approval of a standard for the licensing of the whole SEPs (aggregate royalty) within the
SSO itself or through an authorized third-party agency similar to the patent pool administrator.
Then, each patentee of SEPs will receive a share of the aggregate royalty proportional to the
number of SEPs.
The main advantage of this approach for FRAND licensing is the setting of the total
royalty that the implementers should pay independent of the number of SEPs for a given
standard. The main drawback of this approach for FRAND licensing is the determination of
SEPs because most of candidates for SEPs cannot be granted from a patent office upon final
approval of a standard.77
Additional disadvantage of this approach is the cost and inefficiency
in the royalty setting process, which may affect the standardization process itself.
Arbitration for FRAND licensing
Another method to resolve FRAND disputes at the SSO level and through the ICT
industry players’ voluntary collaboration is to utilize arbitration as proposed by Lemley and
Shapiro.78
The arbitration approach to FRAND licensing is to adopt the negotiation scheme of
traditional baseball-style arbitration. In the baseball-style arbitration, each party proposes a
reasonable licensing royalty and the arbitrator choose one. To make the arbitration binding, the
arbitration clause can be included in the IPR policies of SSOs that a patentee of SEPs should
agree to. In the case of unwilling licensee, the patentee can sue for monetary damages and
injunctive relief.
77
Almost all patents are filed during the standardization process, and thus, they will still be in pending and their
claims can be changed log time after final approval of a standard.
78
Mark A. Lemley & Carl Shapiro, A Simple Approach to Setting Reasonable Royalties for Standard-Essential
Patents (Stanford Public Law Working Paper No. 2243026 , 2013), available at
http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=2243026.
26
The main advantage of this approach for FRAND licensing is its simplicity and
efficiency for the determination of the royalty. The main drawback of this approach for FRAND
licensing is to establish expertise and authority of the arbitrator by which not only the parties of
the license but courts honor his or her decision.79
IV. Recommendations
A. FRAND Royalty and Injunctive Relief
Hybrid approach to FRAND royalty
As can be seen in the previous discussion, there is no consensus among the ICT industry
players to accept either the traditional entire product or rather the smallest saleable component,
as FRAND royalty base. A method to resolve disagreement about FRAND royalty base may be
a hybrid approach to royalty base that was suggested by the 3G licensing platform.80
The 3G
licensing platform, which is the licensing organization for 3G mobile SEPs, adopted reference
market value of the entire product as a royalty base, if the product consists of several functional
blocks. For example, if the product performs 3G mobile communication and other functions that
give values to the users of the product, the royalty base only take into account the value
proportional to the 3G mobile communication function embedded in the entire product. Thus, if
a mobile phone of price T includes a component of price A for mobile communication function
79
The court can refuse to recognize or enforce an arbitration award (i.e., the decision of an arbitrator) only under
limited circumstances provided in the New York Convention, such as “against public policy.” The Convention is
available at: http://www.uncitral.org/uncitral/uncitral_texts/arbitration/NYConvention.html.
80
Larry Goldstein & Brian Kearsey, Technology Patent Licensing 154 (Aspatore Books 2004).
27
and other components of price B for other independent functions and multiple components of
price C for common functions supporting both mobile communication function and other
independent functions, FRAND royalty base for mobile communication is A in the smallest
saleable component approach and T in the entire market approach. In the hybrid approach to
FRAND royalty, however, FRAND royalty base for mobile communication is A + C x [A/(A+B)]
taking into account the net contribution of the multiple components for common functions to
mobile communication. Consequently, FRAND royalty base is a compromise value between the
two extremes such that it is the entire product value including only the smallest saleable function
contributed by the patented feature of a SEP.
Ex Post Pseudo-pool Approach
The main concept of the ex post pseudo-pool approach to FRAND licensing is to set the
total royalty that the implementers should pay independent of the number of SEPs for a given
standard, which was the main advantage of the ex ante pseudo-pool approach. The patentees of
SEPs for a given standard may form the ex post pseudo-pool to set the total royalty. The
difference from the traditional patent pools is that the ex post pseudo-pool does not administrate
the licensing processes. The ex post pseudo-pool can also evaluate whether the patentees’ SEPs
are truly the SEPs through an authorized third-party agency or experts. Then, each participating
members of the ex post pseudo-pool can receive a share of the FRAND royalty proportional to
the number of true SEPs.
Law and economic analysis for injunctive relief
28
It would be valuable to study the adequate compensation and availability of the injunctive
relief for SEPs at the fundamental level beyond courts’ interpretations based on contractual
obligation of FRAND commitments.81
The fundamental goal of providing certain exclusive
rights for a limited time to one’s invention is to create incentives which can maximize social
welfare (the difference between the economic benefits and costs) provided by the patent system.
The economic benefits of the patent system are well described in the justification theories for the
patent system.82
The most familiar justification of the patents system is that the patent system encourages
useful inventions to society by providing patent rights as an incentive. The presumption of this
justification is that motivating useful inventions always serve society beneficially and there
would be no inventions without the patent system. Therefore, under this justification of the
patent system, stronger the patent protection the more useful inventions will result in. This
justification is called ex ante justification of the patent system because it focuses on the role of
the patent system before the creation of inventions.83
The next justification of patent system is that the patent system induces commercial
exploitation of inventions.84
The rational of this justification is that, absent patent protection,
inventions would not be commercially exploited further due to fear of free ride on the inventions.
Thus, under this justification of the patent system, exclusive rights, like the real property rights,
are necessary to promote efficient use of inventions for maximizing the social welfares.
81
Apple, Inc. v. Motorola, Inc., No. 1:11-cv-08540 (N.D. Ill. 2012); Microsoft Co., v. Motorola, Inc., No. 2:10-cv-
01823-JLR (W.D. WA 2012).
82
See, e.g., The Patent Prospector, Patent Economics,
http://www.patenthawk.com/blog/2005/04/patent_economics_part_4_incent.html (last visited Oct. 1, 2013).
83
Mark Lemley, ‘Ex Ante Versus Ex Post Justifications for Intellectual Property,’ 71 U. Chi L. Rev. 129 (2004).
84
Id.
29
Therefore, a case study for social welfare provided by SEPs85
taking into accounts the
benefit provided by interoperability and the cost provided by the strong patent protections would
provide another insight for the adequate compensation and availability of the injunctive relief for
SEPs.
B. Alternative Methods for FRAND Licensing
Collaboration between SSOs and patent offices for ex ante FRAND licensing
As an alternative method to resolve FRAND disputes, ex ante FRAND licensing at the
SSO level by adapting IPR policies of SSOs was proposed. By the ex ante FRAND licensing,
FRAND royalty can exclude the ex post hold up value that SEPs acquired after a standardized
technology was adopted widely in the relevant technology market. The main drawback of this
approach for FRAND licensing is the determination of SEPs because a patent office cannot grant
most of candidates for SEPs upon final approval of a standard. A possible solution to this
drawback would be the collaboration between SSOs and patent offices for ex ante granting of
patents filed by the participating members of SSOs cover the standardized technology through an
accelerated patent prosecution in the patent offices. 86
For example, IPR policies of SSOs can include a clause for the requirement of
accelerated patent prosecution of patents relate to any proposal submitted during the
85
A good example for the case study will be the 3G mobile communications because there are enough information
for empirical analysis.
86
Ex ante granting of SEPs would be possible utilizing the existing accelerated patent prosecution program in the
patent offices. For example, USPTO operates the expedited examination of patent applications such as Prioritized
Examination and Accelerated Examination.
30
standardization. Additionally, a SSO and a patent office can make an agreement for
collaboration regarding accelerated patent prosecution of SEP candidate applications.
Establishment of international arbitration agency for FRAND disputes resolution
As another alternative method to resolve FRAND disputes, arbitration approach to
FRAND licensing through ICT industry players’ voluntary collaboration was proposed. By the
arbitration approach to FRAND licensing, FRAND royalty can be proposed by both parties in
licensing agreement. The main drawback of this approach for FRAND disputes resolution is to
establish expertise and authority of the arbitrator. A possible solution to this drawback would be
the collaboration between SSOs and other international authorities.
For example, World Intellectual Property Organization (WIPO) can be a good candidate
for the collaboration because WIPO can select qualified arbitrators and train them for FRAND
disputes resolution.87
Furthermore, WIPO could provide guidelines for evaluating essentiality of
SEPs and reasonable royalty for FRAND licensing. Specifying WIPO as the authorized
arbitration agency in the arbitration clause that is included in the IPR policies of SSOs can make
patentees of SEPs subject to arbitration in WIPO in case there is any dispute concerning FRAND
commitments.
Still, this method, however, does not solve the issue completely because implementers of
SEPs who are not the member of an SSO cannot be make bind the implementers to the
arbitration in WIPO. Thus, it may be necessary to include a special clause that FRAND
commitments and obligation of arbitration in WIPO only applied when implementers of SEPs
agree to resolve any FRAND disputes through arbitration.
87
WIPO can utilize WIPO’s Arbitration and Mediation Center.
31
It would also be valuable to study the possibility of inclusion of relevant provisions
regarding FRAND disputes resolution in the Agreement on Trade-Related Aspects of Intellectual
Property Rights (TRIPS Agreement) like provisions on compulsory licenses of patents.88
V. Conclusion
In this article, I presented the background of Smartphone Patent Wars and
FRAND disputes surrounding SEPs among ICT industry incumbents. FRAND disputes involve
directly concerned industry parties, public policy agencies, and courts. I reviewed in details
courts resolutions, policy measures by regulation agencies, and industry parties’ response
regarding interpretation of FRAND commitments, adequate remedy, availability of injunctive
relief for SEPs, determination of FRAND Royalty, and antitrust matters. I also discussed
potential adverse effects of courts’ resolutions to the ICT industry and alternative methods to
resolve FRAND Disputes at the SSO level and through voluntary collaboration among ICT
industry players.
Considering the increasing disputes regarding SEPs in ICT industry, SSOs, courts, and
regulatory agencies should make more efforts to resolve FRAND disputes. I have tried to
provide a little contribution to the efforts of resolving FRAND disputes through
recommendations and suggestions for further studies.
88
Article 31 of the TRIPS Agreement specifies the compulsory licenses of patents.

More Related Content

What's hot

Ip For Non Lawyers March 4, 2009
Ip For Non Lawyers March 4, 2009 Ip For Non Lawyers March 4, 2009
Ip For Non Lawyers March 4, 2009 eleznik
 
Developing Powerful Brads
Developing Powerful BradsDeveloping Powerful Brads
Developing Powerful Bradsjhreescnm
 
Ip Law And The Internet Presentation (1)
Ip Law And The Internet Presentation (1)Ip Law And The Internet Presentation (1)
Ip Law And The Internet Presentation (1)ElaineLee
 
ETHICS05 - Intellectual Property
ETHICS05 - Intellectual PropertyETHICS05 - Intellectual Property
ETHICS05 - Intellectual PropertyMichael Heron
 
IAM Yearbook 2016_Vringo
IAM Yearbook 2016_VringoIAM Yearbook 2016_Vringo
IAM Yearbook 2016_VringoDavid Cohen
 
Entrepreneurship 101: Managing Intellectual Property with Arshia Tabrizi
Entrepreneurship 101: Managing Intellectual Property with Arshia TabriziEntrepreneurship 101: Managing Intellectual Property with Arshia Tabrizi
Entrepreneurship 101: Managing Intellectual Property with Arshia TabriziMaRS Discovery District
 
BEN Networking - Generating Revenue Through IP February 2012
BEN Networking - Generating Revenue Through IP February 2012BEN Networking - Generating Revenue Through IP February 2012
BEN Networking - Generating Revenue Through IP February 2012Science City Bristol
 
Intellectual property services hyderabad
Intellectual property services hyderabadIntellectual property services hyderabad
Intellectual property services hyderabadAccuprosys
 
Intellectual Property Services
Intellectual Property ServicesIntellectual Property Services
Intellectual Property Servicesaccu6030
 
Stellar TCPA victory press release
Stellar TCPA victory press releaseStellar TCPA victory press release
Stellar TCPA victory press releaseKim Harvey
 
FTC Complaint Against Intel (Actual Document)
FTC Complaint Against Intel (Actual Document)FTC Complaint Against Intel (Actual Document)
FTC Complaint Against Intel (Actual Document)Jon Hansen
 

What's hot (18)

Ip For Non Lawyers March 4, 2009
Ip For Non Lawyers March 4, 2009 Ip For Non Lawyers March 4, 2009
Ip For Non Lawyers March 4, 2009
 
Knobbe Wins 466.7M For Medical Tech Company | Daily Journal
Knobbe Wins 466.7M For Medical Tech Company | Daily JournalKnobbe Wins 466.7M For Medical Tech Company | Daily Journal
Knobbe Wins 466.7M For Medical Tech Company | Daily Journal
 
Developing Powerful Brads
Developing Powerful BradsDeveloping Powerful Brads
Developing Powerful Brads
 
Ip Law And The Internet Presentation (1)
Ip Law And The Internet Presentation (1)Ip Law And The Internet Presentation (1)
Ip Law And The Internet Presentation (1)
 
ETHICS05 - Intellectual Property
ETHICS05 - Intellectual PropertyETHICS05 - Intellectual Property
ETHICS05 - Intellectual Property
 
IAM Yearbook 2016_Vringo
IAM Yearbook 2016_VringoIAM Yearbook 2016_Vringo
IAM Yearbook 2016_Vringo
 
Entrepreneurship 101: Managing Intellectual Property with Arshia Tabrizi
Entrepreneurship 101: Managing Intellectual Property with Arshia TabriziEntrepreneurship 101: Managing Intellectual Property with Arshia Tabrizi
Entrepreneurship 101: Managing Intellectual Property with Arshia Tabrizi
 
BEN Networking - Generating Revenue Through IP February 2012
BEN Networking - Generating Revenue Through IP February 2012BEN Networking - Generating Revenue Through IP February 2012
BEN Networking - Generating Revenue Through IP February 2012
 
RIM
RIMRIM
RIM
 
Intellectual property services hyderabad
Intellectual property services hyderabadIntellectual property services hyderabad
Intellectual property services hyderabad
 
Intellectual Property Services
Intellectual Property ServicesIntellectual Property Services
Intellectual Property Services
 
Stellar TCPA victory press release
Stellar TCPA victory press releaseStellar TCPA victory press release
Stellar TCPA victory press release
 
Handset Subsidies- Don't Shoot the Messenger
Handset Subsidies- Don't Shoot the MessengerHandset Subsidies- Don't Shoot the Messenger
Handset Subsidies- Don't Shoot the Messenger
 
Law: Bill Loginov
Law: Bill LoginovLaw: Bill Loginov
Law: Bill Loginov
 
Intellectual Property
Intellectual PropertyIntellectual Property
Intellectual Property
 
FTC Complaint Against Intel (Actual Document)
FTC Complaint Against Intel (Actual Document)FTC Complaint Against Intel (Actual Document)
FTC Complaint Against Intel (Actual Document)
 
Poster-Template Simplify
Poster-Template SimplifyPoster-Template Simplify
Poster-Template Simplify
 
To Promote Innovation
To Promote InnovationTo Promote Innovation
To Promote Innovation
 

Viewers also liked

테크아이피엠 특허 지식재산 전자신문 기고모음
테크아이피엠 특허 지식재산 전자신문 기고모음테크아이피엠 특허 지식재산 전자신문 기고모음
테크아이피엠 특허 지식재산 전자신문 기고모음Alex G. Lee, Ph.D. Esq. CLP
 
Presentación HMES
Presentación HMESPresentación HMES
Presentación HMESguesta04b80
 
Human Computer Interaction
Human Computer InteractionHuman Computer Interaction
Human Computer Interactiondfg dg
 
Ai One Presentation Semtech 2011 V3
Ai One Presentation Semtech 2011 V3Ai One Presentation Semtech 2011 V3
Ai One Presentation Semtech 2011 V3tom_marsh
 
Biweekly Financial Commentary 08 12 08
Biweekly Financial Commentary 08 12 08Biweekly Financial Commentary 08 12 08
Biweekly Financial Commentary 08 12 08Ant Wong
 
Pacini Apco Firenze
Pacini Apco FirenzePacini Apco Firenze
Pacini Apco Firenzeaprovisi
 
Patent Evaluation Services for Investment Professionals
Patent Evaluation Services for Investment ProfessionalsPatent Evaluation Services for Investment Professionals
Patent Evaluation Services for Investment ProfessionalsAlex G. Lee, Ph.D. Esq. CLP
 
LTE Standard Essential Patents Nokia v InterDigital Analysis 4Q 2013
LTE Standard Essential Patents Nokia v InterDigital Analysis 4Q 2013LTE Standard Essential Patents Nokia v InterDigital Analysis 4Q 2013
LTE Standard Essential Patents Nokia v InterDigital Analysis 4Q 2013Alex G. Lee, Ph.D. Esq. CLP
 
Biweekly Financial Commentary 09 07 20
Biweekly Financial Commentary 09 07 20Biweekly Financial Commentary 09 07 20
Biweekly Financial Commentary 09 07 20Ant Wong
 
Characteristics of Litigated Patents for the IoT(Internet of Things) Connecti...
Characteristics of Litigated Patents for the IoT(Internet of Things) Connecti...Characteristics of Litigated Patents for the IoT(Internet of Things) Connecti...
Characteristics of Litigated Patents for the IoT(Internet of Things) Connecti...Alex G. Lee, Ph.D. Esq. CLP
 
Body systems
Body systemsBody systems
Body systemsAinhize
 
Apache CloudStack: API to UI (STLLUG)
Apache CloudStack: API to UI (STLLUG)Apache CloudStack: API to UI (STLLUG)
Apache CloudStack: API to UI (STLLUG)Joe Brockmeier
 
Stanziale seminario accademia s. luca 19.06.14
Stanziale   seminario accademia  s. luca 19.06.14Stanziale   seminario accademia  s. luca 19.06.14
Stanziale seminario accademia s. luca 19.06.14Alain Denis
 

Viewers also liked (20)

테크아이피엠 특허 지식재산 전자신문 기고모음
테크아이피엠 특허 지식재산 전자신문 기고모음테크아이피엠 특허 지식재산 전자신문 기고모음
테크아이피엠 특허 지식재산 전자신문 기고모음
 
Presentación HMES
Presentación HMESPresentación HMES
Presentación HMES
 
Human Computer Interaction
Human Computer InteractionHuman Computer Interaction
Human Computer Interaction
 
Magazine Part 2
Magazine Part 2Magazine Part 2
Magazine Part 2
 
Ai One Presentation Semtech 2011 V3
Ai One Presentation Semtech 2011 V3Ai One Presentation Semtech 2011 V3
Ai One Presentation Semtech 2011 V3
 
Biweekly Financial Commentary 08 12 08
Biweekly Financial Commentary 08 12 08Biweekly Financial Commentary 08 12 08
Biweekly Financial Commentary 08 12 08
 
Ilhas Falklands
Ilhas FalklandsIlhas Falklands
Ilhas Falklands
 
Pacini Apco Firenze
Pacini Apco FirenzePacini Apco Firenze
Pacini Apco Firenze
 
Patent Evaluation Services for Investment Professionals
Patent Evaluation Services for Investment ProfessionalsPatent Evaluation Services for Investment Professionals
Patent Evaluation Services for Investment Professionals
 
Jon-Paul\'s Visual Resume
Jon-Paul\'s Visual ResumeJon-Paul\'s Visual Resume
Jon-Paul\'s Visual Resume
 
LTE Standard Essential Patents Nokia v InterDigital Analysis 4Q 2013
LTE Standard Essential Patents Nokia v InterDigital Analysis 4Q 2013LTE Standard Essential Patents Nokia v InterDigital Analysis 4Q 2013
LTE Standard Essential Patents Nokia v InterDigital Analysis 4Q 2013
 
Chateaux d'Europe
Chateaux d'EuropeChateaux d'Europe
Chateaux d'Europe
 
Parque chinês
Parque chinêsParque chinês
Parque chinês
 
Biweekly Financial Commentary 09 07 20
Biweekly Financial Commentary 09 07 20Biweekly Financial Commentary 09 07 20
Biweekly Financial Commentary 09 07 20
 
Filo
FiloFilo
Filo
 
Tips, Tools and Techniques to Boost Your Wellness Effort
Tips, Tools and Techniques to Boost Your Wellness EffortTips, Tools and Techniques to Boost Your Wellness Effort
Tips, Tools and Techniques to Boost Your Wellness Effort
 
Characteristics of Litigated Patents for the IoT(Internet of Things) Connecti...
Characteristics of Litigated Patents for the IoT(Internet of Things) Connecti...Characteristics of Litigated Patents for the IoT(Internet of Things) Connecti...
Characteristics of Litigated Patents for the IoT(Internet of Things) Connecti...
 
Body systems
Body systemsBody systems
Body systems
 
Apache CloudStack: API to UI (STLLUG)
Apache CloudStack: API to UI (STLLUG)Apache CloudStack: API to UI (STLLUG)
Apache CloudStack: API to UI (STLLUG)
 
Stanziale seminario accademia s. luca 19.06.14
Stanziale   seminario accademia  s. luca 19.06.14Stanziale   seminario accademia  s. luca 19.06.14
Stanziale seminario accademia s. luca 19.06.14
 

Similar to (Microsoft v. Google) Smartphone Patent Wars: Legal & Policy Issues of Standard Essential Patents in ICT Industry

Smartphone Standard Essential Patent: FRAND Disputes 101
Smartphone Standard Essential Patent: FRAND Disputes 101Smartphone Standard Essential Patent: FRAND Disputes 101
Smartphone Standard Essential Patent: FRAND Disputes 101Alex G. Lee, Ph.D. Esq. CLP
 
Standard essential patents
Standard essential patentsStandard essential patents
Standard essential patentsTal Lavian Ph.D.
 
LTE Patents Licensing Royalty Issues with Connected Cars Licensing Journal Ja...
LTE Patents Licensing Royalty Issues with Connected Cars Licensing Journal Ja...LTE Patents Licensing Royalty Issues with Connected Cars Licensing Journal Ja...
LTE Patents Licensing Royalty Issues with Connected Cars Licensing Journal Ja...Alex G. Lee, Ph.D. Esq. CLP
 
Unpacking the Royalty Stack
Unpacking the Royalty StackUnpacking the Royalty Stack
Unpacking the Royalty StackErik Oliver
 
AIPJ_25.4_June2015_hoad&polites
AIPJ_25.4_June2015_hoad&politesAIPJ_25.4_June2015_hoad&polites
AIPJ_25.4_June2015_hoad&politesRichard Hoad
 
Monetization Strategy for Standard Essential Patents 4Q 2013
Monetization Strategy for Standard Essential Patents 4Q 2013Monetization Strategy for Standard Essential Patents 4Q 2013
Monetization Strategy for Standard Essential Patents 4Q 2013Alex G. Lee, Ph.D. Esq. CLP
 
Patenting in Mobile Application and Technology
Patenting in Mobile Application and TechnologyPatenting in Mobile Application and Technology
Patenting in Mobile Application and TechnologyIndicThreads
 
Licensing SEPs: When are License Terms Fair, Reasonable and Non-Discriminatory?
Licensing SEPs: When are License Terms Fair, Reasonable and Non-Discriminatory?Licensing SEPs: When are License Terms Fair, Reasonable and Non-Discriminatory?
Licensing SEPs: When are License Terms Fair, Reasonable and Non-Discriminatory?Florence Competition Programme
 
Vietnam – Intellectual Property Rights – 2015
Vietnam – Intellectual Property Rights – 2015Vietnam – Intellectual Property Rights – 2015
Vietnam – Intellectual Property Rights – 2015Dr. Oliver Massmann
 
Chapter 5 - Timing of Entry
Chapter 5 - Timing of EntryChapter 5 - Timing of Entry
Chapter 5 - Timing of EntryWahyu Yudistira
 
What is 'Fair' and 'Reasonable'? Lessons on the Concept of FRAND from EU Comp...
What is 'Fair' and 'Reasonable'? Lessons on the Concept of FRAND from EU Comp...What is 'Fair' and 'Reasonable'? Lessons on the Concept of FRAND from EU Comp...
What is 'Fair' and 'Reasonable'? Lessons on the Concept of FRAND from EU Comp...FSR Communications and Media
 
Technology management
Technology managementTechnology management
Technology managementUfuk Kılıç
 
Ipdr munich mar 2017 (david perkins)
Ipdr munich mar 2017 (david perkins)Ipdr munich mar 2017 (david perkins)
Ipdr munich mar 2017 (david perkins)JAMSInternational
 
Smartphone Patent Wars: Legal & Policy Issues of Standard Essential Patens in...
Smartphone Patent Wars: Legal & Policy Issues of Standard Essential Patens in...Smartphone Patent Wars: Legal & Policy Issues of Standard Essential Patens in...
Smartphone Patent Wars: Legal & Policy Issues of Standard Essential Patens in...Alex G. Lee, Ph.D. Esq. CLP
 
Protecting innovation
Protecting innovation Protecting innovation
Protecting innovation wahyu0916
 
Npe antitrust challenges - writing sample
Npe   antitrust challenges - writing sampleNpe   antitrust challenges - writing sample
Npe antitrust challenges - writing sampleBinQiang Liu
 
Standards 2010: Prospects and Challenges for Standards Development in the Nex...
Standards 2010: Prospects and Challenges for Standards Development in the Nex...Standards 2010: Prospects and Challenges for Standards Development in the Nex...
Standards 2010: Prospects and Challenges for Standards Development in the Nex...Chuck Allen
 
Lesi 2017 annual conference apr 2017.part 1 (david perkins)
Lesi 2017 annual conference  apr 2017.part 1 (david perkins)Lesi 2017 annual conference  apr 2017.part 1 (david perkins)
Lesi 2017 annual conference apr 2017.part 1 (david perkins)JAMSInternational
 
Standardizing Patent License Agreements
Standardizing Patent License AgreementsStandardizing Patent License Agreements
Standardizing Patent License Agreementsnewmandavid
 

Similar to (Microsoft v. Google) Smartphone Patent Wars: Legal & Policy Issues of Standard Essential Patents in ICT Industry (20)

Smartphone Standard Essential Patent: FRAND Disputes 101
Smartphone Standard Essential Patent: FRAND Disputes 101Smartphone Standard Essential Patent: FRAND Disputes 101
Smartphone Standard Essential Patent: FRAND Disputes 101
 
Standard essential patents
Standard essential patentsStandard essential patents
Standard essential patents
 
LTE Patents Licensing Royalty Issues with Connected Cars Licensing Journal Ja...
LTE Patents Licensing Royalty Issues with Connected Cars Licensing Journal Ja...LTE Patents Licensing Royalty Issues with Connected Cars Licensing Journal Ja...
LTE Patents Licensing Royalty Issues with Connected Cars Licensing Journal Ja...
 
Unpacking the Royalty Stack
Unpacking the Royalty StackUnpacking the Royalty Stack
Unpacking the Royalty Stack
 
AIPJ_25.4_June2015_hoad&polites
AIPJ_25.4_June2015_hoad&politesAIPJ_25.4_June2015_hoad&polites
AIPJ_25.4_June2015_hoad&polites
 
Monetization Strategy for Standard Essential Patents 4Q 2013
Monetization Strategy for Standard Essential Patents 4Q 2013Monetization Strategy for Standard Essential Patents 4Q 2013
Monetization Strategy for Standard Essential Patents 4Q 2013
 
Patenting in Mobile Application and Technology
Patenting in Mobile Application and TechnologyPatenting in Mobile Application and Technology
Patenting in Mobile Application and Technology
 
Licensing SEPs: When are License Terms Fair, Reasonable and Non-Discriminatory?
Licensing SEPs: When are License Terms Fair, Reasonable and Non-Discriminatory?Licensing SEPs: When are License Terms Fair, Reasonable and Non-Discriminatory?
Licensing SEPs: When are License Terms Fair, Reasonable and Non-Discriminatory?
 
Vietnam – Intellectual Property Rights – 2015
Vietnam – Intellectual Property Rights – 2015Vietnam – Intellectual Property Rights – 2015
Vietnam – Intellectual Property Rights – 2015
 
Chapter 5 - Timing of Entry
Chapter 5 - Timing of EntryChapter 5 - Timing of Entry
Chapter 5 - Timing of Entry
 
What is 'Fair' and 'Reasonable'? Lessons on the Concept of FRAND from EU Comp...
What is 'Fair' and 'Reasonable'? Lessons on the Concept of FRAND from EU Comp...What is 'Fair' and 'Reasonable'? Lessons on the Concept of FRAND from EU Comp...
What is 'Fair' and 'Reasonable'? Lessons on the Concept of FRAND from EU Comp...
 
Technology management
Technology managementTechnology management
Technology management
 
Ipdr munich mar 2017 (david perkins)
Ipdr munich mar 2017 (david perkins)Ipdr munich mar 2017 (david perkins)
Ipdr munich mar 2017 (david perkins)
 
Strategic Patent Management in Mobile Telecom
Strategic Patent Management in Mobile TelecomStrategic Patent Management in Mobile Telecom
Strategic Patent Management in Mobile Telecom
 
Smartphone Patent Wars: Legal & Policy Issues of Standard Essential Patens in...
Smartphone Patent Wars: Legal & Policy Issues of Standard Essential Patens in...Smartphone Patent Wars: Legal & Policy Issues of Standard Essential Patens in...
Smartphone Patent Wars: Legal & Policy Issues of Standard Essential Patens in...
 
Protecting innovation
Protecting innovation Protecting innovation
Protecting innovation
 
Npe antitrust challenges - writing sample
Npe   antitrust challenges - writing sampleNpe   antitrust challenges - writing sample
Npe antitrust challenges - writing sample
 
Standards 2010: Prospects and Challenges for Standards Development in the Nex...
Standards 2010: Prospects and Challenges for Standards Development in the Nex...Standards 2010: Prospects and Challenges for Standards Development in the Nex...
Standards 2010: Prospects and Challenges for Standards Development in the Nex...
 
Lesi 2017 annual conference apr 2017.part 1 (david perkins)
Lesi 2017 annual conference  apr 2017.part 1 (david perkins)Lesi 2017 annual conference  apr 2017.part 1 (david perkins)
Lesi 2017 annual conference apr 2017.part 1 (david perkins)
 
Standardizing Patent License Agreements
Standardizing Patent License AgreementsStandardizing Patent License Agreements
Standardizing Patent License Agreements
 

More from Alex G. Lee, Ph.D. Esq. CLP

[Presentation] Webinar on Patent Management and Patent Asset STO in the ChatG...
[Presentation] Webinar on Patent Management and Patent Asset STO in the ChatG...[Presentation] Webinar on Patent Management and Patent Asset STO in the ChatG...
[Presentation] Webinar on Patent Management and Patent Asset STO in the ChatG...Alex G. Lee, Ph.D. Esq. CLP
 
Metaverse x AI x Web3 x Sustainability Convergence
Metaverse x AI x  Web3 x Sustainability ConvergenceMetaverse x AI x  Web3 x Sustainability Convergence
Metaverse x AI x Web3 x Sustainability ConvergenceAlex G. Lee, Ph.D. Esq. CLP
 
Tokenization, Securitization, Monetization of Real-World Assets
Tokenization, Securitization, Monetization of Real-World AssetsTokenization, Securitization, Monetization of Real-World Assets
Tokenization, Securitization, Monetization of Real-World AssetsAlex G. Lee, Ph.D. Esq. CLP
 
Maximizing Innovation through ChatGPT Powered Patent Analysis
Maximizing Innovation through ChatGPT Powered Patent AnalysisMaximizing Innovation through ChatGPT Powered Patent Analysis
Maximizing Innovation through ChatGPT Powered Patent AnalysisAlex G. Lee, Ph.D. Esq. CLP
 
Maximizing AI Business Value Creation Utilizing Patents
Maximizing AI Business Value Creation Utilizing PatentsMaximizing AI Business Value Creation Utilizing Patents
Maximizing AI Business Value Creation Utilizing PatentsAlex G. Lee, Ph.D. Esq. CLP
 
Real-World Assets STO + Institutional DeFi Integration
Real-World Assets STO + Institutional DeFi IntegrationReal-World Assets STO + Institutional DeFi Integration
Real-World Assets STO + Institutional DeFi IntegrationAlex G. Lee, Ph.D. Esq. CLP
 
Metaverse & Web3 Technology Innovation & Business Development
Metaverse & Web3 Technology Innovation & Business DevelopmentMetaverse & Web3 Technology Innovation & Business Development
Metaverse & Web3 Technology Innovation & Business DevelopmentAlex G. Lee, Ph.D. Esq. CLP
 
웹3.0기반 메타버스 응용을 위한 NFT 가치개발과 가치평가 특강
웹3.0기반 메타버스 응용을 위한 NFT 가치개발과 가치평가 특강웹3.0기반 메타버스 응용을 위한 NFT 가치개발과 가치평가 특강
웹3.0기반 메타버스 응용을 위한 NFT 가치개발과 가치평가 특강Alex G. Lee, Ph.D. Esq. CLP
 
NFT for Web3 Based Metaverse Monetization Webinar.pdf
NFT for Web3 Based Metaverse Monetization Webinar.pdfNFT for Web3 Based Metaverse Monetization Webinar.pdf
NFT for Web3 Based Metaverse Monetization Webinar.pdfAlex G. Lee, Ph.D. Esq. CLP
 
FAME UNIVERSE Fashion NFT Monetization Platform Introduction
FAME UNIVERSE Fashion NFT Monetization Platform IntroductionFAME UNIVERSE Fashion NFT Monetization Platform Introduction
FAME UNIVERSE Fashion NFT Monetization Platform IntroductionAlex G. Lee, Ph.D. Esq. CLP
 
NAVIGATING THE METAVERSE (Wiley) One Page Book Summary
NAVIGATING THE METAVERSE (Wiley)  One Page Book SummaryNAVIGATING THE METAVERSE (Wiley)  One Page Book Summary
NAVIGATING THE METAVERSE (Wiley) One Page Book SummaryAlex G. Lee, Ph.D. Esq. CLP
 

More from Alex G. Lee, Ph.D. Esq. CLP (20)

[Presentation] Webinar on Patent Management and Patent Asset STO in the ChatG...
[Presentation] Webinar on Patent Management and Patent Asset STO in the ChatG...[Presentation] Webinar on Patent Management and Patent Asset STO in the ChatG...
[Presentation] Webinar on Patent Management and Patent Asset STO in the ChatG...
 
Metaverse x AI x Web3 x Sustainability Convergence
Metaverse x AI x  Web3 x Sustainability ConvergenceMetaverse x AI x  Web3 x Sustainability Convergence
Metaverse x AI x Web3 x Sustainability Convergence
 
Tokenization, Securitization, Monetization of Real-World Assets
Tokenization, Securitization, Monetization of Real-World AssetsTokenization, Securitization, Monetization of Real-World Assets
Tokenization, Securitization, Monetization of Real-World Assets
 
Maximizing Innovation through ChatGPT Powered Patent Analysis
Maximizing Innovation through ChatGPT Powered Patent AnalysisMaximizing Innovation through ChatGPT Powered Patent Analysis
Maximizing Innovation through ChatGPT Powered Patent Analysis
 
Maximizing AI Business Value Creation Utilizing Patents
Maximizing AI Business Value Creation Utilizing PatentsMaximizing AI Business Value Creation Utilizing Patents
Maximizing AI Business Value Creation Utilizing Patents
 
Real-World Assets STO + Institutional DeFi Integration
Real-World Assets STO + Institutional DeFi IntegrationReal-World Assets STO + Institutional DeFi Integration
Real-World Assets STO + Institutional DeFi Integration
 
Metaverse x Web3 Interoperability Overview
Metaverse x Web3 Interoperability OverviewMetaverse x Web3 Interoperability Overview
Metaverse x Web3 Interoperability Overview
 
AI for Metaverse x Web3 Overview
AI for Metaverse x Web3 OverviewAI for Metaverse x Web3 Overview
AI for Metaverse x Web3 Overview
 
NFT Web3 Metaverse Global Leaders Roundtable
NFT Web3 Metaverse Global Leaders RoundtableNFT Web3 Metaverse Global Leaders Roundtable
NFT Web3 Metaverse Global Leaders Roundtable
 
Fame Universe Introduction
Fame Universe IntroductionFame Universe Introduction
Fame Universe Introduction
 
Metaverse Fashion Overview
Metaverse Fashion OverviewMetaverse Fashion Overview
Metaverse Fashion Overview
 
Global Metaverse Fashion Innovators Roadshow
Global Metaverse Fashion Innovators RoadshowGlobal Metaverse Fashion Innovators Roadshow
Global Metaverse Fashion Innovators Roadshow
 
NFT Financialization Overview
NFT Financialization OverviewNFT Financialization Overview
NFT Financialization Overview
 
Metaverse & Web3 Technology Innovation & Business Development
Metaverse & Web3 Technology Innovation & Business DevelopmentMetaverse & Web3 Technology Innovation & Business Development
Metaverse & Web3 Technology Innovation & Business Development
 
NFT Monetization Innovation Webinar
NFT Monetization Innovation WebinarNFT Monetization Innovation Webinar
NFT Monetization Innovation Webinar
 
웹3.0기반 메타버스 응용을 위한 NFT 가치개발과 가치평가 특강
웹3.0기반 메타버스 응용을 위한 NFT 가치개발과 가치평가 특강웹3.0기반 메타버스 응용을 위한 NFT 가치개발과 가치평가 특강
웹3.0기반 메타버스 응용을 위한 NFT 가치개발과 가치평가 특강
 
NFT for Web3 Based Metaverse Monetization Webinar.pdf
NFT for Web3 Based Metaverse Monetization Webinar.pdfNFT for Web3 Based Metaverse Monetization Webinar.pdf
NFT for Web3 Based Metaverse Monetization Webinar.pdf
 
FAME UNIVERSE Fashion NFT Monetization Platform Introduction
FAME UNIVERSE Fashion NFT Monetization Platform IntroductionFAME UNIVERSE Fashion NFT Monetization Platform Introduction
FAME UNIVERSE Fashion NFT Monetization Platform Introduction
 
NAVIGATING THE METAVERSE (Wiley) One Page Book Summary
NAVIGATING THE METAVERSE (Wiley)  One Page Book SummaryNAVIGATING THE METAVERSE (Wiley)  One Page Book Summary
NAVIGATING THE METAVERSE (Wiley) One Page Book Summary
 
FAME Universe Introduction
FAME Universe IntroductionFAME Universe Introduction
FAME Universe Introduction
 

Recently uploaded

Mondelez State of Snacking and Future Trends 2023
Mondelez State of Snacking and Future Trends 2023Mondelez State of Snacking and Future Trends 2023
Mondelez State of Snacking and Future Trends 2023Neil Kimberley
 
Call Girls Navi Mumbai Just Call 9907093804 Top Class Call Girl Service Avail...
Call Girls Navi Mumbai Just Call 9907093804 Top Class Call Girl Service Avail...Call Girls Navi Mumbai Just Call 9907093804 Top Class Call Girl Service Avail...
Call Girls Navi Mumbai Just Call 9907093804 Top Class Call Girl Service Avail...Dipal Arora
 
The Coffee Bean & Tea Leaf(CBTL), Business strategy case study
The Coffee Bean & Tea Leaf(CBTL), Business strategy case studyThe Coffee Bean & Tea Leaf(CBTL), Business strategy case study
The Coffee Bean & Tea Leaf(CBTL), Business strategy case studyEthan lee
 
Enhancing and Restoring Safety & Quality Cultures - Dave Litwiller - May 2024...
Enhancing and Restoring Safety & Quality Cultures - Dave Litwiller - May 2024...Enhancing and Restoring Safety & Quality Cultures - Dave Litwiller - May 2024...
Enhancing and Restoring Safety & Quality Cultures - Dave Litwiller - May 2024...Dave Litwiller
 
Catalogue ONG NUOC PPR DE NHAT .pdf
Catalogue ONG NUOC PPR DE NHAT      .pdfCatalogue ONG NUOC PPR DE NHAT      .pdf
Catalogue ONG NUOC PPR DE NHAT .pdfOrient Homes
 
7.pdf This presentation captures many uses and the significance of the number...
7.pdf This presentation captures many uses and the significance of the number...7.pdf This presentation captures many uses and the significance of the number...
7.pdf This presentation captures many uses and the significance of the number...Paul Menig
 
Call Girls in Gomti Nagar - 7388211116 - With room Service
Call Girls in Gomti Nagar - 7388211116  - With room ServiceCall Girls in Gomti Nagar - 7388211116  - With room Service
Call Girls in Gomti Nagar - 7388211116 - With room Servicediscovermytutordmt
 
Insurers' journeys to build a mastery in the IoT usage
Insurers' journeys to build a mastery in the IoT usageInsurers' journeys to build a mastery in the IoT usage
Insurers' journeys to build a mastery in the IoT usageMatteo Carbone
 
VIP Kolkata Call Girl Howrah 👉 8250192130 Available With Room
VIP Kolkata Call Girl Howrah 👉 8250192130  Available With RoomVIP Kolkata Call Girl Howrah 👉 8250192130  Available With Room
VIP Kolkata Call Girl Howrah 👉 8250192130 Available With Roomdivyansh0kumar0
 
GD Birla and his contribution in management
GD Birla and his contribution in managementGD Birla and his contribution in management
GD Birla and his contribution in managementchhavia330
 
RE Capital's Visionary Leadership under Newman Leech
RE Capital's Visionary Leadership under Newman LeechRE Capital's Visionary Leadership under Newman Leech
RE Capital's Visionary Leadership under Newman LeechNewman George Leech
 
Pharma Works Profile of Karan Communications
Pharma Works Profile of Karan CommunicationsPharma Works Profile of Karan Communications
Pharma Works Profile of Karan Communicationskarancommunications
 
Ensure the security of your HCL environment by applying the Zero Trust princi...
Ensure the security of your HCL environment by applying the Zero Trust princi...Ensure the security of your HCL environment by applying the Zero Trust princi...
Ensure the security of your HCL environment by applying the Zero Trust princi...Roland Driesen
 
DEPED Work From Home WORKWEEK-PLAN.docx
DEPED Work From Home  WORKWEEK-PLAN.docxDEPED Work From Home  WORKWEEK-PLAN.docx
DEPED Work From Home WORKWEEK-PLAN.docxRodelinaLaud
 
Russian Faridabad Call Girls(Badarpur) : ☎ 8168257667, @4999
Russian Faridabad Call Girls(Badarpur) : ☎ 8168257667, @4999Russian Faridabad Call Girls(Badarpur) : ☎ 8168257667, @4999
Russian Faridabad Call Girls(Badarpur) : ☎ 8168257667, @4999Tina Ji
 
Sales & Marketing Alignment: How to Synergize for Success
Sales & Marketing Alignment: How to Synergize for SuccessSales & Marketing Alignment: How to Synergize for Success
Sales & Marketing Alignment: How to Synergize for SuccessAggregage
 
Monte Carlo simulation : Simulation using MCSM
Monte Carlo simulation : Simulation using MCSMMonte Carlo simulation : Simulation using MCSM
Monte Carlo simulation : Simulation using MCSMRavindra Nath Shukla
 
Regression analysis: Simple Linear Regression Multiple Linear Regression
Regression analysis:  Simple Linear Regression Multiple Linear RegressionRegression analysis:  Simple Linear Regression Multiple Linear Regression
Regression analysis: Simple Linear Regression Multiple Linear RegressionRavindra Nath Shukla
 

Recently uploaded (20)

Mondelez State of Snacking and Future Trends 2023
Mondelez State of Snacking and Future Trends 2023Mondelez State of Snacking and Future Trends 2023
Mondelez State of Snacking and Future Trends 2023
 
Call Girls Navi Mumbai Just Call 9907093804 Top Class Call Girl Service Avail...
Call Girls Navi Mumbai Just Call 9907093804 Top Class Call Girl Service Avail...Call Girls Navi Mumbai Just Call 9907093804 Top Class Call Girl Service Avail...
Call Girls Navi Mumbai Just Call 9907093804 Top Class Call Girl Service Avail...
 
The Coffee Bean & Tea Leaf(CBTL), Business strategy case study
The Coffee Bean & Tea Leaf(CBTL), Business strategy case studyThe Coffee Bean & Tea Leaf(CBTL), Business strategy case study
The Coffee Bean & Tea Leaf(CBTL), Business strategy case study
 
Enhancing and Restoring Safety & Quality Cultures - Dave Litwiller - May 2024...
Enhancing and Restoring Safety & Quality Cultures - Dave Litwiller - May 2024...Enhancing and Restoring Safety & Quality Cultures - Dave Litwiller - May 2024...
Enhancing and Restoring Safety & Quality Cultures - Dave Litwiller - May 2024...
 
Catalogue ONG NUOC PPR DE NHAT .pdf
Catalogue ONG NUOC PPR DE NHAT      .pdfCatalogue ONG NUOC PPR DE NHAT      .pdf
Catalogue ONG NUOC PPR DE NHAT .pdf
 
7.pdf This presentation captures many uses and the significance of the number...
7.pdf This presentation captures many uses and the significance of the number...7.pdf This presentation captures many uses and the significance of the number...
7.pdf This presentation captures many uses and the significance of the number...
 
Call Girls in Gomti Nagar - 7388211116 - With room Service
Call Girls in Gomti Nagar - 7388211116  - With room ServiceCall Girls in Gomti Nagar - 7388211116  - With room Service
Call Girls in Gomti Nagar - 7388211116 - With room Service
 
Forklift Operations: Safety through Cartoons
Forklift Operations: Safety through CartoonsForklift Operations: Safety through Cartoons
Forklift Operations: Safety through Cartoons
 
Insurers' journeys to build a mastery in the IoT usage
Insurers' journeys to build a mastery in the IoT usageInsurers' journeys to build a mastery in the IoT usage
Insurers' journeys to build a mastery in the IoT usage
 
VIP Kolkata Call Girl Howrah 👉 8250192130 Available With Room
VIP Kolkata Call Girl Howrah 👉 8250192130  Available With RoomVIP Kolkata Call Girl Howrah 👉 8250192130  Available With Room
VIP Kolkata Call Girl Howrah 👉 8250192130 Available With Room
 
GD Birla and his contribution in management
GD Birla and his contribution in managementGD Birla and his contribution in management
GD Birla and his contribution in management
 
RE Capital's Visionary Leadership under Newman Leech
RE Capital's Visionary Leadership under Newman LeechRE Capital's Visionary Leadership under Newman Leech
RE Capital's Visionary Leadership under Newman Leech
 
Best Practices for Implementing an External Recruiting Partnership
Best Practices for Implementing an External Recruiting PartnershipBest Practices for Implementing an External Recruiting Partnership
Best Practices for Implementing an External Recruiting Partnership
 
Pharma Works Profile of Karan Communications
Pharma Works Profile of Karan CommunicationsPharma Works Profile of Karan Communications
Pharma Works Profile of Karan Communications
 
Ensure the security of your HCL environment by applying the Zero Trust princi...
Ensure the security of your HCL environment by applying the Zero Trust princi...Ensure the security of your HCL environment by applying the Zero Trust princi...
Ensure the security of your HCL environment by applying the Zero Trust princi...
 
DEPED Work From Home WORKWEEK-PLAN.docx
DEPED Work From Home  WORKWEEK-PLAN.docxDEPED Work From Home  WORKWEEK-PLAN.docx
DEPED Work From Home WORKWEEK-PLAN.docx
 
Russian Faridabad Call Girls(Badarpur) : ☎ 8168257667, @4999
Russian Faridabad Call Girls(Badarpur) : ☎ 8168257667, @4999Russian Faridabad Call Girls(Badarpur) : ☎ 8168257667, @4999
Russian Faridabad Call Girls(Badarpur) : ☎ 8168257667, @4999
 
Sales & Marketing Alignment: How to Synergize for Success
Sales & Marketing Alignment: How to Synergize for SuccessSales & Marketing Alignment: How to Synergize for Success
Sales & Marketing Alignment: How to Synergize for Success
 
Monte Carlo simulation : Simulation using MCSM
Monte Carlo simulation : Simulation using MCSMMonte Carlo simulation : Simulation using MCSM
Monte Carlo simulation : Simulation using MCSM
 
Regression analysis: Simple Linear Regression Multiple Linear Regression
Regression analysis:  Simple Linear Regression Multiple Linear RegressionRegression analysis:  Simple Linear Regression Multiple Linear Regression
Regression analysis: Simple Linear Regression Multiple Linear Regression
 

(Microsoft v. Google) Smartphone Patent Wars: Legal & Policy Issues of Standard Essential Patents in ICT Industry

  • 1. 1 Smartphone Patent Wars: Legal & Policy Issues of Standard Essential Patens in ICT Industry by Alex G. Lee1 As represented by “Smartphone Patent Wars,” patents for smartphones became the most important strategic competition tool among market leaders. Especially, patents for mobile communication standards, which are the so-called ‘Standard Essential Patents (SEPs),’ became the center of legal and policy debates regarding their intellectual property rights (IPRs). The author provides the implications of recent courts’ resolutions regarding FRAND (Fair, Reasonable And Non Discriminatory) disputes to the ICT (Information and Communications Technology) industry and provide several alternative options for resolving FRAND disputes. The author contends that the current concerted resolutions in courts and regulation agencies can results in adverse effects to the ICT industry. The author also contends the main drawback of the recent proposals to resolve the disputes surrounding SEPs through the ex ante FRAND licensing and the ICT industry players’ voluntary collaboration. From the analysis of ICT industry players’ response to the outcomes of court resolutions, the author contends a compromising way to provide FRAND Royalty adopting arguments from both sides of the disputes. The author also contends a practical improvement to the voluntary collaboration proposals to resolve the disputes surrounding SEPs. 1 Alex Geunho Lee, Ph.D., earned his J.D. from the Suffolk University Law School. He thanks to Professor Christopher Gibson for directing this thesis paper. He also thanks to Professor Michael L. Rustad, Ms. Hee-Eun Kim, Mr. Larry M. Goldstein and Professor Stephen Y. Chow for valuable comments.
  • 2. 2 Table of Contents I. Introduction II. A Holistic Review of Current Issues in FRAND Disputes A. Interpretation of FRAND Commitments B. Determination of FRAND Royalty C. Antitrust Issue III. Implications for ICT Industry A. Response of ICT Industry to the Courts’ Resolutions B. Potential Adverse Effects of Courts’ Resolutions C. Alternative Methods to Resolve FRAND Disputes IV. Recommendations A. FRAND Royalty and Injunctive Relief B. Alternative Methods for FRAND Licensing V. Conclusion
  • 3. 3 I. Introduction Smartphones, which are the convergence products of computers and mobile communication devices, are now revolutionizing our life style, business activities, and society as a whole. Current smartphone boom started when the first iPhone was released on June 29, 2007. According to a market research by comScore in January of 2013, 129.4 million people in the United States owned smartphones, which is about 55 percent of mobile subscribes.2 Globally, total smartphone sales reached $250 billion in 2012.3 The heavy competition among smartphone manufactures for establishing competitive market position in the newly formed lucrative business has led to recent intensive patent infringement lawsuits, which are the so-called ‘Smartphone Patent Wars.’ Smartphone Patent Wars began in 2009 when Nokia sued Apple and Apple countersued Nokia.4 Then, the Smartphone Patent Wars extended globally involving new players from smartphone manufactures to makers of smartphone related products such as tablets and entertainment devices.5 When Apple accused Motorola and Samsung of infringement of its user interface software and design patents, Motorola and Samsung counter-attacked through new patent lawsuits utilizing their patents for mobile communication standards, which are the so-called 2 Score Press Releases, U.S. Smartphone Subscriber Market Share, http://www.comscore.com/Insights/Press_Releases/2013/3/comScore_Reports_January_2013_U.S._Smartphone_Su bscriber_Market_Share (last visited April 1, 2013). 3 AP News, Smartphone 4Q Sales Rise 36 PCT Led by Samsung, http://bigstory.ap.org/article/smartphone-4q-sales- rise-36-pct-led-samsung (last visited April 1, 2013). 4 Wikipedia, Smartphone wars, http://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Smartphone_wars (last visited April 1, 2013). 5 Competing smartphone manufactures can be grouped as iOS group represented by Apple, Android group represented by Google and its subsidiary Motorola, and Windows Mobile group represented by Microsoft by the operating systems of the smartphones.
  • 4. 4 ‘Standard Essential Patents (SEPs).’ SEPs were a natural choice for Motorola and Samsung, which were incumbents in mobile communication industry and holders of strong mobile patent portfolios, to counter-attack Apple, which is the computer industry incumbent, and thus, lacks in SEPs for mobile communications. SEPs encompass intellectual property rights (IPRs) for the standardized technologies. Usually, all the essential aspects of standardized technologies are specified in standard specifications.6 Thus, SEPs can be defined as patents that include one or more claims that are infringed by the implementation of certain standard specifications. Consequently, Apple’s standard-compatible products that implement the standard specifications for mobile communications may infringe SEPs of Motorola and Samsung. Therefore, Motorola and Samsung sought to demand a sales ban of Apple’s standard-compatible products in addition to monetary relief. The outcomes, however, were different than expected in the usual SEPs litigation scenario.7 Standards are often developed and set-up through the standardization process by the standard setting organizations (SSOs).8 If the adopted standards are covered by some patents owned by the members that proposed the adopted standards, the members become the patentees of SEPs. The patentee of SEPs may have market power in the relevant technology market 6 To facilitate interoperability among the industry players, participants in the development of standards establish specifications for the essential components of the standardized technology. “The standard specifications, however, do not define all the technical aspects for commercial products implementation. 7 The main advantage of using SEPs is their easy of proof characteristic for infringement analysis. Once a patent in litigation is proved to be a SEP, it was an assumption that the accused standard-compatible product should infringe the SEP. Therefore, the infringer reluctantly came to the negotiation table for a licensing of the SEP. 8 In this article, SSO will be used interchangeably with the traditional term SDO (Standard Developing Organization). During the standardization process, participating members propose their preferred standard applications to the technical committees of SSOs. Board members of the technical committees, then, review the proposed standard applications and submit the adopted applications to the technical committees to decide whether to accept the adopted applications through a voting among the participating members. See, e.g., Wikipedia, Standards Organization, http://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Standards_organization (last visited October 1, 2013).
  • 5. 5 because the industry may be locked-in to using the standard and the value of SEPs becomes significantly enhanced. Thus, the patentee can demand and obtain unreasonably high royalty payments – hold up value - due to very high switching cost to alternative technology the implementer should pay.9 Thus, the patent hold up occurs when a patentee of SEPs demands unreasonably higher license fees after the standard is widely adopted than could have been obtained before the standard was implemented. To avoid the patent holdup problem, a majority of the SSOs require that the members participating in the standardization process to agree ex ante to license their SEPs under fair, reasonable, and nondiscriminatory (FRAND)10 terms ex post to any implementers of the standard. The members’ agreements to license their SEPs under FRAND terms are usually called FRAND commitments. In general, FRAND commitments are interpreted as enforceable contractual obligations between a member and an SSO.11 An implementer of the standard is a third-party beneficiary of FRAND commitments and therefore entitled to a license of SEPs.12 FRAND commitments can also be interpreted as encumbrances of SEPs as in servitudes for real 9 See, e.g., Mark A Lemley & Carl Shapiro, Patent Holdup and Royalty Stacking, 85 Tex. L. Rev, 1991, 2007 (2007). 10 In this article, FRAND will be used interchangeably with RAND (reasonable, and nondiscriminatory). In FRAND, fair means to underlying licensing terms are not un-fair. Reasonable means that the licensing royalty rates should not be excessively higher than the value of benefits that can be acquired by the license. Non-discriminatory means licensors treat all licensees in a similar manner in licensing agreements. See, e.g., Wikipedia, Reasonable and non- discriminatory licensing, http://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Reasonable_and_non-discriminatory_licensing (last visited October 1, 2013). 11 Mark A. Lemley, Intellectual Property Rights and Standard-Setting Organizations, 90 Cal. L. Rev. 1889, 1909- 1918 (2002). 12 Here, the beneficiary includes both member and nonmember of the SSO. See, e.g., Lemley, supra note 10, at 1915.
  • 6. 6 properties.13 Thus, FRAND commitments create FRAND-encumbered IPRs that run with SEPs.14 An implementer of the standard holds entitlements of FRAND commitments to SEPs. Considering all the interest parties surrounding FRAND commitments, the disputes over SEPs in Smartphone Patent Wars lead to FRAND disputes involving directly concerned parties, public policy initiated interruptions by regulation agencies, and courts’ interpretations about FRAND commitments. These disputes take on an increasing importance in the information and communications technology (ICT) industry. The main purpose of this article is to understand the implications of recent courts’ resolutions regarding FRAND disputes to the ICT industry and provide several alternative options for resolving FRAND disputes. I contended that the current concerted resolutions in courts and regulation agencies can results in adverse effects to the ICT industry. I also contended the main drawback of the recent proposals to resolve the disputes surrounding SEPs through the ex ante FRAND licensing and the ICT industry players’ voluntary collaboration. From the analysis of ICT industry players’ response to the outcomes of court resolutions, I contended a compromising way to provide FRAND Royalty adopting arguments from both sides of the disputes. I also contended a practical improvement to the voluntary collaboration proposals to resolve the disputes surrounding SEPs. This article is organized as follows. In Section II, I will present a holistic review of current issues in FRAND disputes. This section includes details about major issues in FRAND disputes, courts resolutions, and policy measures by regulation agencies: How to interpret FRAND commitments?; When is a patentee of SEPs entitled to an injunctive relief?; Is an 13 Jay P. Kesan & Carol M. Hayes, FRAND's Forever: Standards, Patent Transfers, and Licensing Commitments (Illinois Public Law Research Paper No. 13-31, 2013), available at http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=2226533. p. 88 14 If the SEPs are sold to someone else, FRAND commitments automatically transfer to the new SEPs holder.
  • 7. 7 exclusion order for SEPs in the International Trade Commission (ITC) available?; What is the appropriate remedial compensations for SEPs?; Can exploitations of SEPs without limitation be liable for antitrust violation? Having understood the background of smartphone patent wars surrounding SEPs and holistic review of current issues in FRAND disputes, I introduce implications of current legal and policy issues surrounding SEPs for the ICT industry in Section III: Will the ICT industry players agree to the outcomes of court resolutions?; Is there any possibility that the outcomes of the current concerted resolutions in courts and regulation agencies affect the ICT industry players adversely? Are there any better ways to resolve the disputes surrounding SEPs through the ICT industry players’ voluntary collaboration? In Section IV, I present a set of recommendations in light of the analysis above: Hybrid approach to FRAND royalty; Law and economic analysis for injunctive relief; Collaboration between SSOs and patent offices for ex ante FRAND licensing; and Establishment of international arbitration agency for FRAND disputes resolution. I conclude this article in Section V. II. A Holistic Review of Current Issues in FRAND Disputes A. Interpretation of FRAND Commitments FRAND commitments under SSOs’ IPR polices
  • 8. 8 Many SSOs adopt IPR polices to implement their members’ agreement to FRAND commitments. However, definition of FRAND terms is not specified in SSOs’ IPR polices.15 Thus, what is meant by fair, reasonable, and nondiscriminatory is left to the interpretation of parties who are involved in the FRAND commitments. Furthermore, SSOs’ IPR polices normally do not specify the conditions for contractual agreement under the FRAND commitments to form binding obligations to the parties. The reason behind the fact that SSOs’ IPR polices normally do not specify the conditions for contractual agreement under the FRAND commitments can be understand as an effort to avoid risk of any antitrust liabilities.16 SSOs often involve agreements among horizontal competitors. Thus, specifying the FRAND commitments can be considered as raising traditional antitrust concerns such as price fixing, exclusive dealing, etc.17 Consequently, the absence of clear definitions about FRAND terms for binding obligations in SSOs’ IPR polices is the main causes of FRAND disputes surrounding SEPs.18 15 See, e.g., Rudi Bekkers & Andrew Updegrove, A study of IPR policies and practices of a representative group of Standards Setting Organizations worldwide, project report on Intellectual Property Management in standard setting processes, STEP, 2012, http://home.tm.tue.nl/rbekkers/nas/Bekkers_Updegrove_NAS2012_main_report.pdf (last visited June 1, 2013).The report exampled twelve representative SSOs such as International Organization for Standardization (ISO), International Electrotechnical Commission (IEC), International Telecommunication Union (ITU), Institute of Electrical and Electronics Engineers (IEEE), European Telecommunications Standards Institute (ETSI), American National Standards Institute (ANSI), Internet Engineering Task Force (IETF), Organization for the Advancement of Structured Information Standards (OASIS), VMEBus International Trade Association (VITA). World Wide Web Consortium (W3C), High Definition Multimedia Interface (HDMI) Forum, and Nearfield Communications (NFC) Forum. Among the 8 SSOs that adopted FRAND commitments, none of the IPR policies specified the definition of the FRAND terms. 16 Anne Layne-Farrar, A. Jorge Padilla & Richard Schmalensee, Pricing Patents for Licensing in Standard-Setting Organizations: Making Sense of FRAND Commitments, 74 Antitrust L.J. 671, 678-79 (2007). 17 U.S.DEPARTMENT OF JUSTICE & FEDERAL TRADE COMMISSION, ANTITRUST GUIDELINES FOR THE LICENSING OF INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY, 1995, available at http://www.usdoj.gov/atr/public/guidelines/0558.pdf. (last visited Feb. 1, 2013). 18 See, e.g., Kai-Uwe Kühn, Fiona Scott Morton & Howard Shelanski, Standard Setting Organizations Can Help Solve the Standard Essential Patents Licensing Problem (CPI ANTITRUST CHRON. March special issue, 2013), available at https://www.competitionpolicyinternational.com/assets/Free/ScottMortonetalMar-13Special.pdf. For example, if a patentee of SEPs offers a royalty for the licensing agreement to a potential licensee to comply with
  • 9. 9 Courts’ interpretation of the FRAND commitments In Microsoft, Co. v. Motorola, Inc.19 , the court interpreted FRAND commitments such that the patentee should grant the implementer a license to its SEPs under FRAND terms. The Microsoft court ruled that the implementer was not required to negotiate for FRAND terms prior to filing a breach of contract lawsuit. The court reasoned that, as a third-party beneficiary for FRAND commitment between a patentee of SEPs and a SSO, Microsoft had an enforceable legal right to a FRAND license from the patentee prior to a licensing agreement. Thus, the ruling means that implementer’s offer and negotiation for a patent license were not conditions precedent for the patentee to obligate to FRAND commitments. Consequently, if the implementer believes that the patentee’s offer for the license does not meet FRAND terms, it can bring a lawsuit for breach of FRAND commitments and dispute resolution. On the other hand, in Orange-Book- Standard20 , the German Federal Supreme Court (BGH) ruled that the implementer was required to make an unconditional and reasonable offer to license on FRAND terms prior to patent infringement. The Orange-Book- Standard case involved SEPs for compact disk standard which was known as the Orange Book. As a defense for the patent infringement, the defendant in Orange-Book- Standard argued that the plaintiff’s enforcement of its SEPs violated EU’s antitrust law because the plaint abused its dominant FRAND commitment and the licensee disagree with the royalty and refuse to proceed the licensing negotiation, the only way to resolve the dispute is to file a law suit for court’s decision about setting a reasonable royalty. 19 Microsoft, Co. v. Motorola, Inc., No. 2:10-cv-01823-JLR (W.D. WA 2012), Dkt. No. 465 at 12-17. (This lawsuit involves two SSOs’ SEPs – SEPs for IEEE’s 802.11 Wireless LAN standard and ITU’s H.264 video coding standard. To comply with IEEE’s IPR policy, Motorola submitted a Letters of Assurance promising that it will grant a license under reasonable rates, terms, and conditions in a non-discriminatory basis to an unrestricted number of implementers. To comply with ITU’s IPR policy, Motorola also submitted a Patent Statement and Licensing Declaration declaring that it will grant a license under reasonable terms and conditions in a non-discriminatory basis to an unrestricted number of implementers). 20 Orange-Book-Standard, Bundesgerichtshof (BGH), May 6, 2009, KZR 39/06.
  • 10. 10 position in the market. The BGH in Orange-Book- Standard, however, ruled that making an unconditional offer to license on FRAND was the precondition for the defendant to asset the anti-competitive defense. Furthermore, the BGH in Orange-Book- Standard also rule that the patentee of SEPs did not need to accept the offer if it believed that the implementer’s offer was not reasonable and unconditional. Consequently, the implementer has burden to prove that the patentee refuses the license notwithstanding the offer was unconditional and reasonable within the meaning of FRAND terms. The above mentioned two cases show a clear difference in interpretation of the FRAND commitments. The Microsoft court interprets that patents of SEPs should offer a reasonable royalty to the implementer and if the implementer believes that the patentee’s offered royalty for the license does not meet FRAND terms, it can bring a lawsuit for breach of FRAND commitments. On the other hand, the Orange-Book- Standard court interprets that the implementer should offer a reasonable royalty to the patents of SEPs and if the patents of SEPs believes that the implementer’s offered royalty for the license does not meet FRAND terms, it can bring a lawsuit for patent infringement. Even if both cases provided different conditions for FRAND commitment, they indicated the importance of determination of FRAND terms in resolving FRAND dispute. Especially, a court should provide the reasonable royalty for licensing agreements under FRAND terms - FRAND royalty. FRAND royalty will be discussed in detail later of this section. Availability of injunctive relief for SEPs
  • 11. 11 In Apple, Inc. v. Motorola, Inc.,21 the court interpreted FRAND commitments such that the patentee “implicitly acknowledged that a royalty is an adequate compensation for a patent license.” Thus the patentee of SEPs is not entitled to an injunctive relief because “the inadequacy of monetary relief22 ” is required for the entitlement of the injunctive relief and FRAND royalty would provide the adequate remedy.23 In Microsoft, Co., v. Motorola, Inc.,24 the court also ruled that a FRAND royalty provides an adequate compensation because a patentee “has always been required to grant a license” to an implementer at FRAND royalty for its SEPs and the patentee has not been irreparably harmed. On the other hand, in Orange-Book- Standard,25 the BGH ruled that a patentee of SEPs is entitled to injunctive relief. The court interpretation is such that the implementer was required to make an unconditional offer to license on FRAND terms prior to patent infringement. The court reasoned that the infringement of SEPs itself shows the implementer’s unwillingness to make an unconditional offer to license on FRAND terms. Therefore, an injunctive relief is available for infringed SEPs. However, the court also held that an injunctive relief is not available for infringed SEPs “if the patentee discriminates or inequitably obstructs” to an implementer’s unconditional offer to license on FRAND terms and conditions. 21 Apple, Inc. v. Motorola, Inc., No. 1:11-cv-08540 (N.D. Ill. 2012), Dkt. No. 1038 at 18-19. This case involves SEPs for 3G mobile communications (UMTS) standardized by ETSI. 22 This is one of four factors that should be considered in granting injunctive relief for patent infringement in eBay, Inc. v. MercExchange, L.L.C., 547 U.S. 388 (2006). The other three factors are 1. The patentee has suffered an irreparable injury; 2. A remedy in equity is warranted considering the balance of hardships between the patentee and infringer; 3. The public interest would not be disserved by an injunctive relief. 23 Id. at 21. 24 Microsoft, Co., v. Motorola, Inc., No. 2:10-cv-01823-JLR (W.D. WA 2012), Dkt. No. 607 at 12-15. 25 Orange-Book-Standard, Bundesgerichtshof (BGH), May 6, 2009, KZR 39/06.
  • 12. 12 Availability of exclusion order for SEPs in ITC In Motorola Mobility, Inc. v. Apple Inc.,26 the Administrative Law Judge ruled that FRAND commitments do not preclude an exclusion order for SEPs in ITC (International Trade Commission). The ITC reasoned that its investigations to determine whether to issue an exclusion order banning importation of infringing product for violations of section 337 of the Tariff Act of 1930 (19 U.S.C. § 1337) have a wider scope than investigations in courts because its interests include public interest in addition to private interest. In Spansion, Inc. v. ITC,27 the court hold that the ITC is not required to apply the traditional four-factor test of the Supreme Court’s eBay decision for injunctive relief used by federal district courts. The court reasoned that legislative history of the amendments to Section 337 indicates that Congress intended injunctive relief to be the normal remedy for a Section 337 violation.28 In response to the ITC’s ruling of availability of exclusion order for SEPs two US government agencies- Department of Justice (DOJ) and Patent & Trademark Office (PTO) - jointly announced that in some instances the remedy of an exclusion order may be inconsistent with the public interest.29 The agencies insisted that SPEs cannot be used to block sales or imports of infringing products in cases where the patentee tries to exploit the SEPs’ market 26 Motorola Mobility, Inc. v. Apple Inc., In the Matter of Certain Wireless Communication Devices, Portable Music and Data Processing Devices, Computers and Components Thereof, ITC Inv. No. 337-TA-745. 27 Spansion, Inc. v. ITC, 629 F.3d 1331 (Fed. Cir. 2010). 28 In Tariff Act of 1930, Congress eliminated the monetary remedy of §316 of the Tariff Act of 1922. This represents a legislative determination that an injunction is the only available remedy for violations of Section 337. Furthermore, Congress amended Section 337 to remove the requirement of proof of harm to domestic industry in 1988. This represents a legislative determination that it is unnecessary to show irreparable harm to the patentee. 29 U.S.DEPARTMENT OF JUSTICE & U.S. PATENT & TRADEMARK OFFIC, Policy Statement on Remedies for Standards-Essential Patents , 2013, http:// www.justice.gov/atr/public/guidelines/290994.pdf (last visited Feb. 1, 2013).
  • 13. 13 power through exclusion order for pressuring an implementer to accept unreasonably high royalty against its FREND commitments.30 The agencies reasoned that such activity and resulting exclusion order might be anti-competitive, and thus, harm consumers. The agencies also mentioned that, in cases in which the implementer acts beyond the scope of FRAND commitments, such as refusing to license on FRAND terms and conditions, an exclusion order may still be appropriate.31 In response to the ITC’s ruling of availability of exclusion order for Samsung’s SEP of 3G mobile communications,32 the USTR (U.S. Trade Representative) vetoed against the ITC’s ruling.33 The USTR exercised its latest veto of disapproving the ITC’s ruling 26 years ago. The USTR reasoned that exploitation of SEPs can effect on competitive conditions in the US economy and the US consumers adversely. B. Determination of FRAND Royalty Appropriate remedial compensation for SEPs Another issue in FRAND disputes is the appropriate remedial compensation for SEPs. In Apple, Inc. v. Motorola, Inc.,34 the court ruled that a FRAND royalty should not reflect the ex post hold up value that SEPs acquired after a standardized technology was adopted widely in the 30 Id. at 6. 31 Id. at 7. 32 Samsung, Inc. v. Apple Inc., Certain Electronic Devices, Including Wireless Communication Devices, Portable Music and Data Processing Devices, and Tablet Computers, ITC Inv. No. 337-TA-794. 33 USTR representative Michael Froman’s letter to the ITC, http://www.ustr.gov/sites/default/files/08032013%20Letter_1.PDF (last visited Aug. 20, 2013). 34 Apple, Inc. v. Motorola, Inc., No. 1:11-cv-08540 (N.D. Ill. 2012), Dkt. No. 1038 at 18.
  • 14. 14 relevant technology market. Thus, the FRAND royalty can be a measure of value the implementer can obtain by adopting the standardized technology over available alternatives at the time the standard was specified. In other words, FRAND royalty can be the maximum royalty amount that a licensee would be willing to pay in return for the incremental profit produced by implementing the patented standardized technology over the alternatives.35 Therefore, hypothetical negotiation framework to determine FRAND royalty subject to the incremental value over alternatives at the time the standard was specified can be applied. Opponents of the above court’s reasoning for FRAND royalty, however, argued that a FRAND royalty should be determined as a reasonable royalty based on a hypothetical negotiation at the time of infringement36 because the damages adequate to compensate would be damages that place the patentee in the position it would have been but for the infringement.37 Opponents also argued that the FRAND royalty can be measured from a comparable licensing price in the relevant licensing marketplace. On the other hand, proponents of the above court’s reasoning for FRAND royalty, however, argued that market value for FRAND royalty could not be used as providing the reliable FRAND royalty levels unless the comparable licensing royalty has not been affected by enhanced market power of SEPs.38 FRAND royalty base and rate 35 Lance E. Gunderson, Stephen E. Dell & Scott W. Cragun, The Analytic Approach as a Technique to Determine a Reasonable Royalty, in ECONOMIC DAMAGES IN INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY: A HANDS-ONGUIDE TO LITIGATION 181, 182 (Daniel Slottje ed., 2006). 36 See, e.g., Motorola’s argument in Apple, Inc. v. Motorola, Inc., Case: 12-1548 (Fed. Cir. 2012), Dkt. No. 131 at 19. 37 Brooktree Corp. v. Advanced Micro-Devices, Inc., 977 F.2d 1555, 1579 (Fed. Cir. 1992). 38 Anne Layne-Farrar, A. Jorge Padilla & Richard Schmalensee., supra note 15.
  • 15. 15 Two important questions that the disputes about the appropriate remedial compensations for SEPs typically leave open are FRAND royalty base and rate. Courts may use a royalty base equal to the entire market value of an infringing product if “the patented feature is the basis for consumer demand” for the entire product.39 If the patented feature is not the basis for consumer demand for the entire product, the royalty base should reflect only the contribution of the patented feature to consumer demand.40 Thus, if a product consists of many components, the royalty base can be the market value of the relevant component to consumer demand created by the patented feature.41 In LaserDynamics, Inc. v. Quanta Computer, Inc.,42 the court ruled that the royalty base can be the smallest saleable component that embodies the patented feature. By this reasoning, the FRAND royalty base may be the smallest saleable component that embodies the relevant SEPs. After the FRAND royalty base was determined, a royalty rate for a specific SEP can be calculated by taking account of the economic contribution of the specific SEP to the smallest saleable component that is used in determination of the FRAND royalty base. Additionally, to evaluate whether a license meets FRAND requirement, a court must also ensure that the royalty rate reflects the total royalty burden on that component to avoid royalty stacking problem.43 39 Marine Polymer Techs., Inc. v. HemCon, Inc., 672 F.3d 1350, 1360 (Fed. Cir. 2012) (en banc). 40 UNILOC USA, INC. v. MICROSOFT CORP., 632 F.3d 1292, 1318–19 (Fed. Cir. 2011). (When a standard is incorporated into only one component of a multi-component product, royalties based on the value of the entire product tend to compensate SEP holders for numerous technologies and features beyond those covered by their patents, thereby overcompensating them and leading to royalty stacking (the overall cumulative royalty costs for a given standard in excess of the total product cost)) 41 This situation is especially prevalent in the ICT industry. 42 LaserDynamics, Inc. v. Quanta Computer, Inc., 694 F.3d 51, 68 (Fed. Cir. 2012). 43 Even if the royalty rate for individual SEP is low, total royalty rates can be excessively large if the implementer should have licenses multiple SEPs from different patentees. See, e.g., Lemley, M. A., & Shapiro, C., supra note 8. "Royalty stacking refers to situations in which a single product potentially infringes on many patents, and thus may bear multiple royalty burdens. The term 'royalty stacking' reflects the fact that, from the perspective of the firm
  • 16. 16 Guidelines for FRAND royalty determination In Microsoft Co., v. Motorola, Inc.,44 the court provided basic guidelines for assessing FRAND royalty. The Microsoft court devised the guidelines based on the Georgia- Pacific analysis of the reasonable royalty45 modified to take into account SSOs’ primary goals for requiring FRAND commitments. The court provided five primary goals for adopting FRAND commitments: 1. Promotion of widespread adoption of SSOs’ standards; 2. Avoidance of patent hold-up; 3. Avoidance of royalty stacking; 4. Creation of valuable standards; 5. Exclusion of hold-up value in the reasonable royalty. The court, then, modified the Georgia- Pacific factors to account for the five primary goals for requiring FRAND commitments. The key modifications to the Georgia-Pacific factors that the court utilizes in its procedures for FRAND royalty determination are as follows. making the product in question, all of the different claims for royalties must be added or 'stacked' together to determine the total royalty burden borne by the product if the firm is to sell that product free of patent litigation." 44 Microsoft Co., v. Motorola, Inc., No. 2:10-cv-01823-JLR (W.D. WA 2013), Dkt. No. 681 at 25-41. 45 Georgia-Pacific Corp. v. U.S. Plywood Corp., 318 F. Supp. 1116, 1120 (S.D.N.Y. 1970). (Fifteen factors for determining reasonable royalty are as follows. 1. Royalties patentee receives for licensing the patent in suit; 2. Rates licensee pays for use of other comparable to the patent in suit; 3. Nature and scope of license in terms of exclusivity and territory / customer restrictions; 4. Licensor’s established policy and marketing program to maintain patent monopoly by not licensing others to use the invention; 5. Commercial relationship between licensor and licensee, such as whether they are competitors or inventor and promoter; 6. Effect of selling the patented specialty in promoting sales of other products of the licensee; the existing value of the invention to the licensor as a generator of sales of his non-patented items; and the extent of such derivative or convoyed sales; 7. Duration of patent and term of license; 8. Established profitability of the products made under the patent, its commercial success and its current popularity; 9. Utility and advantages of patent property over old modes and devices ; 10. The nature of the patented invention; the character of the commercial embodiment of it as owned and produced by the licensor; and the benefit of those who have used the invention; 11. The extent to which the infringer has made use of the invention and the value of such use; 12. The portion of profit or selling price customarily allowed for the use of the invention; 13. The portion of realizable profit attributable to the invention as distinguished from non-patented elements, significant features / improvements added by the infringer, the manufacturing process or business risks; 14. Opinion testimony of qualified experts; 15. Outcome from hypothetical arm’s length negotiation at the time of infringement began)
  • 17. 17 First, the court modified the term ‘an established royalty’ in the Georgia-Pacific factor 1 as a royalty established through negotiation under FRAND commitments. By this modification, the court could consider a royalty in a patent pool for the specific SEPs at issue or comparable licensing transactions as a candidate for the royalty established through negotiation under FRAND commitments. Next, the court tried to capture only the ex ante value based on any contribution of the patented technology to the standard with respect to the Georgia-Pacific factors 6 and 8. Here, the ex ante value is an economic value of patented technology excluding value added by being included in the standard. Thus, the ex ante value is comply to the FRAND commitments because it the economic value of patented technology itself without involvement of hold-up value.46 Then, the court evaluated FRAND royalty for the value of a SEP determined through the hypothetical negotiation on the contribution to the standard itself and to the implementer’s products with respect to the Georgia-Pacific factors 10 and 11.47 C. Antitrust Issue 46 Microsoft Co., v. Motorola, Inc., No. 2:10-cv-01823-JLR (W.D. WA 2013), Dkt. No. 681 at 39. 47 See, e.g., In re INNOV A TIO IP VENTURES, LLC, No. 1:11-cv-09308 (N.D. Ill. 2013), Dkt. No. 975 at 84-86. (The court applied the Microsoft court’s guidelines to calculate FRAND royalty of WiFi SEPs. The court calculated the royalty cap using the average profit margin of the WiFi chips that cover all the implemented features of the WiFi standard in the infringing products. Then, the court calculated FRAND royalty by multiplying the average profit margin to the contribution of patentee’s SEPs to the profit and pro rata share of patentee’s SEPs to the total number of WiFi SEPs providing similar contribution to the profit.)
  • 18. 18 The final issue in FRAND disputes is whether the exploitations of SEPs without any limitation can be liable for antitrust violation. Generally, it is not presumed that holding a patent means its owners have market power in the context of antitrust violation analysis.48 However, a patentee of SEPs may have market power in the relevant technology market because the industry may be locked-in to using the standard and all products must be compatible with the standard. Thus, if the patentee of SEPs exploits SEPs for excluding competitors in the revenant market, the exploitation may be considered as abuse of market power created by the standard, with a specific intent to maintain or strengthen its monopolistic market power.49 In Rambus, Inc. v. Fed. Trade Comm’n,50 the court ruled that Rambus did not violate Section 2 of Sherman Act as claimed by Federal Trade Commission (FTC) that Rambus’s failure to disclose SEPs during the standardization process was exclusionary and anticompetitive conduct. The court reasoned that Rambus’s failure to disclose SEPs in breach of FRAND commitments did not have an anticompetitive effect. Thus, the mere breach of FRAND commitments is not enough to show anticompetitive behavior of a patentee of SEPs.51 On the other hand, the European Commission, which is the European Union's competition authority, announced that the patentee of SEPs in breaching of FRAND commitments could potentially be subject to proceedings under Article 102 TFEU.52 The 48 35 U.S.C. Section 271(d); Illinois Tool Works Inc. v. Independent Ink, Inc., 547 U.S. 28 (2006). 49 The patentee of SEPs can be liable for violation of section 2 of Sherman Act. 50 Rambus, Inc. v. Fed. Trade Comm’n, 522 F.3d 456 (D.C. Cir. 2008). 51 In Vizio, Inc. v. Funai Elec. Co. Ltd., 2010 WL 7762624 (C.D. Cal. 2010), the court reasoned that more aggressive anticompetitive activity than mere attempt to harm competition is required to prove antitrust liability. 52 TEUF (Treaty on the Functioning of the European Union) Article 102 prohibits any abuse of dominant market position.
  • 19. 19 European Commission issued a statement of objections to Samsung’s exploitation of its SEPs in bringing a patent lawsuit against Apple for breach of FRAND commitments.53 III. Implications for ICT Industry Having understood the current issues in FRAND disputes and courts’ decisions, I turn my attention now to the implications of current legal and policy issues surrounding SEPs for the ICT industry. I first discuss ICT industry players’ response to the outcomes of court resolutions. I then discuss any potential adverse effects of the outcomes of the current concerted resolutions in courts and regulation agencies to the ICT industry. Finally, I discuss the recent proposals to resolve the disputes surrounding SEPs through the ICT industry players’ voluntary collaboration. A. Response of ICT Industry to the Courts’ Resolutions Will the ICT industry players agree to the outcomes of courts resolution that injunctive relief is not available for SEPs? In response to the court ruling that patentees of SEPs are not entitled to an injunctive relief,54 Motorola agued in its responsive brief55 that the district court violated Supreme Court 53 European Commission Press Releases, http://europa.eu/rapid/press-release_IP-12-1448_en.htm (last visited April 1, 2013): “Samsung's seeking of injunctions against Apple in various EU Member States on the basis of its mobile phone SEPs amounts to an abuse of a dominant position prohibited by EU antitrust rules. While recourse to injunctions is a possible remedy for patent infringements, such conduct may be abusive where SEPs are concerned and the potential licensee is willing to negotiate a license on FRAND terms. The sending of a Statement of Objections does not prejudge the final outcome of the investigation.” 54 Apple, Inc. v. Motorola, Inc., No. 1:11-cv-08540 (N.D. Ill.). 55 Apple, Inc. v. Motorola, Inc., No. 12-8540 (Fed. Cir. 2013), Dkt. No. 131 at 56-74.
  • 20. 20 precedent in eBay56 avoiding the negative consequences of courts’ rulings57 and violating the principle of equity for granting injunction as specified in Patent Act58 by creating a bright-line categorical rule prohibiting injunctive relief for patentees of SEPs under all circumstances. Nokia also expressed its concern about categorical rule prohibiting injunctive relief. Nokia insisted that courts should consider the appropriateness of relief on a case-by-case basis.59 Motorola and Nokia cited the joint statement of DOJ and PTO as a their reasoning for case-by- case approach:60 Even if the agencies insisted that SEPs cannot be used to block sales of infringing products in cases that the patentee tries to exploit the SEPs’ market power through injunction, if the implementer is acting beyond the scope of FRAND commitments such as refusing to license on FRAND terms, however, an injunction may still be appropriate.61 BlackBerry also expressed its position against the categorical rule banning injunctions because the categorical rule can ruin a balanced approach between providing exclusive right for contributing innovation and fair competition in the marketplace.62 On the other hand, Intel argued that allowing injunction for SEPs could open a door for a patentee of SEPs to exploit SEPs for unreasonable compensation that would distort fair 56 eBay Inc. v. MercExchange, LLC, 547 U.S. 388 (2006). 57 An absolute bar on injunctive relief regarding SEPs would foreclose patent holders’ right for fair compensation and increase patent litigation. 58 35 U.S.C. §283. “The several courts having jurisdiction of cases under this title may grant injunctions in accordance with the principles of equity to prevent the violation of any right secured by patent, on such terms as the court deems reasonable.” 59 Nokia’s amicus briefs with the Federal Circuit: Apple, Inc. v. Motorola, Inc., No. 12-8540 (Fed. Cir. 2013), Dkt. No. 53-1. 60 DOJ & PTO report, supra. note 28. 61 Id. at 7. This means that SEP implementers seeking a license must also respect FRAND obligations, although FRAND commitments bind SEP holders only. 62 BlackBerry’s amicus briefs with the Federal Circuit: Apple, Inc. v. Motorola, Inc., No. 12-8540 (Fed. Cir. 2013), Dkt. No. 154.
  • 21. 21 competition and harm consumers.63 Considering a wide spread use of standard-compatible products, granting injunction for SEPs could create risky precedent against the equitable principal of eBay. Microsoft also expressed its position supporting courts’ decision for banning injunctive relief with respect to SEPs.64 Will the ICT industry players agree to the courts’ determination of FRAND Royalty? Qualcomm expressed its serious concerns about courts’ ruling to diminish the value of SEPs in its comments to FTC.65 Qualcomm insisted that there is nothing wrong with the licensing practice of using the price of the entire end product as the appropriate royalty base, because licensing at the end user device level has been an industry custom in the telecommunications sector. By the telecommunications industry custom, Qualcomm explained that patentees of SEPs usually did not enforce licensing obligation to component manufactures. Therefore, FRAND royalty base cannot be the smallest saleable component that embodies the relevant SEPs. Additionally, Qualcomm reasoned that the contribution of the patented feature to consumer demand should not be limited to components of devices because extended consumers’ benefits are coming from the services provided by the network connecting devices.66 Therefore, 63 Intel’s amicus briefs with the Federal Circuit: Apple, Inc. v. Motorola, Inc., No. 12-8540 (Fed. Cir. 2013) Dkt. No. 137. 64 Microsoft’s amicus briefs with the Federal Circuit: Apple, Inc. v. Motorola, Inc., No. 12-8540 (Fed. Cir. 2013), Dkt. No. 144. 65 Comments of Qualcomm, FTC Standards Workshop, Project No. P11-1204, June 13, 2011, http:// ftc.gov/os/comments/motorolagoogle/563708-00022-85574.pdf (last visited Feb. 1, 2013). 66 According to MIT Technology Review, Smartphones Are Eating the World, March 15, 2013, http://www.technologyreview.com/photoessay/511791/smartphones-are-eating-the-world/ (last visited Feb. 1, 2013), mobile operators’ service market was $1.2 trillion and mobile phone (including smartphone) market was $269 billion globally in 2012. In fact, mobile network operators commonly subsidize mobile phone prices, and thus, consumers actually do not pay the full cost of the phones. Hence, even to base licensing royalties on the cost to the
  • 22. 22 the smallest saleable component that embodies the relevant SEPs is actually the device itself in the telecommunications sector. Furthermore, developing standard technology in mobile telecommunications is a high-risk business. Thus, without strong patent protection and return for R&D, there will be no encouragement for further investment in telecommunications standards. Consequently, artificially diminished royalties on mobile telecommunications standard- compatible products will impede innovation, and thus, harm to the industry and consumers ultimately.67 On the other hand, Cisco, HP, and several other IT companies argued that the use of the entire market value as a royalty base should not be used unless all of the profit of the infringing product is attributed to the features of SEPs.68 Thus, the value of SEPs should be determined by apportion to the contribution actually the patented features made to the accused product. They also insisted that patentees bear the burden of proof for the value of SEPs. B. Potential Adverse Effects of Courts’ Resolutions Traditionally, most of patentees of SEPs do not enforce their SEPs unless a large portion of their revenue is derived from the licensing of SEPs,69 or unless the patentees are accused of consumers of the phone is incorrect, since the phone prices are maintained at an artificially low level by the network operators. 67 Qualcomm also expressed its concern about reverse hold up such that an infringer refuses to negotiate in good faith for a FRAND license. 68 Cisco et al.’s amicus briefs with the Federal Circuit: Apple, Inc. v. Motorola, Inc., No. 12-8540 (Fed. Cir. 2013), Dkt. No. 93. 69 Qualcomm’s licensing revenue reached $1.6 billion in 2012.
  • 23. 23 patent infringement by competitors.70 As the courts resolution for FRAND commitments seriously limit the exploitation of SEPs, patentees of SEPs may seek other ways to exploit SEPs. One possibility is the adoption of “patent privateering.” Patent privateering is a kind of trolling practice by which holders of SEPs assign patent trolls to engage in exploiting their IPRs encumbered by FRAND commitments.71 This kind of outsourcing practice of patent enforcement to patent trolls can adversely affect the ICT industry and consumers. First, patent privateering can increase patent lawsuits significantly because patent trolls do not make products or services, and thus, they do not need to worry about counter lawsuits. Second, patent privateering can harm consumers directly because patent trolls willingly sue consumers instead of manufactures or service provides.72 Another possibility is the increasing activity of developing SEPs without participating in SSOs, and thus, without obligations to FRAND commitments. FRAND commitments bind a patentee who participates in a SSO and agrees to IPR policies of the SSO. If a patentee develops SEPs without participating in a SSO, however, the patentee does not have the contractual obligations to FRAND commitments. Sometimes, developing SEPs without participating in a SSO is possible because some of key aspects of the technologies adopted during the standardization can already be developed by a third party who is not the participating member of the SSO. Thus, if the third party filed a patent 70 A common outcome of the counter-attack is a cross-licensing between the two parties in the dispute. 71 See, e.g., Tom Ewing, Indirect Exploitation of Intellectual Property Rights By Corporations and Investors: IP Privateering and Modern Letters of Marque and Reprisal, 4 HASTINGS SCI. TECH. L.J. 1 (2012). 72 Consumers who simply use an infringing product also infringe the patent: 35 U.S.C. §271. In their article Patent Assertion Entities and Antitrust: Operating Company Patent Transfer (The Antitrust Source April 2013), available at http://www.ropesgray.com/~/media/Files/articles/2013/04/Antitrust-Attacks-on-Patent-Assertion-Entities.pdf, Mark S. Popofsky and Michael D. Laufert provides r several ways to challenge the patent privateering exploiting current antitrust liabilities.
  • 24. 24 covering the technologies adopted as the standard, he or she can further develop it though patent prosecution process to be a SEP. In an actual case, when Adaptix, a subsidiary of a patent troll Acacia Research, sued Ericsson at the ITC for infringement of its 4G LTE SEP,73 Adaptix claimed that it has no obligations to FRAND commitments because it did not participate in ETSI’s LTE standardization procedures. C. Alternative Methods to Resolve FRAND Disputes Ex Ante FRAND licensing To provide a forum for discussion among the different stakeholders regarding FRAND disputes, the ITU organized a one-day workshop74 and a follow-up series of meetings.75 The main purpose of the workshop and meetings was to provide a guide to resolve FRAND disputes at the SSO level by adapting IPR policies of SSOs to the changing needs of the ICT industry. Among several ideas exchanged at the meetings, the workshop introduced one interesting proposal that may resolve FRAND disputes before the standards are fully deployed. The approach to resolve FRAND disputes ex ante is named as a pseudo-pool approach to FRAND licensing.76 The basic concept of the pseudo-pool approach to FRAND licensing is to adopt the licensing scheme of traditional patent pools under the administration of SSOs. Thus, under the pseudo-pool approach, the patentees and potential implementers set the reasonable royalty upon 73 Adaptix, Inc. v. Ericsson, Inc., Certain Wireless Communications Base Stations and Components Thereof, ITC Inv. No. 337-TA-871. 74 ITU Patent Roundtable, http://www.itu.int/en/ITU-T/Workshops-and-Seminars/patent/Pages/default.aspx. 75 TSB Director's Ad Hoc Group, http://www.itu.int/en/ITU-T/ipr/Pages/adhoc.aspx. 76 Jorge Contreras, Fixing FRAND: A Pseudo-Pool Approach to Standards-Based Patent Licensing (Antitrust Law Journal, Fall 2013, Forthcoming) available at http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=2232515.
  • 25. 25 final approval of a standard for the licensing of the whole SEPs (aggregate royalty) within the SSO itself or through an authorized third-party agency similar to the patent pool administrator. Then, each patentee of SEPs will receive a share of the aggregate royalty proportional to the number of SEPs. The main advantage of this approach for FRAND licensing is the setting of the total royalty that the implementers should pay independent of the number of SEPs for a given standard. The main drawback of this approach for FRAND licensing is the determination of SEPs because most of candidates for SEPs cannot be granted from a patent office upon final approval of a standard.77 Additional disadvantage of this approach is the cost and inefficiency in the royalty setting process, which may affect the standardization process itself. Arbitration for FRAND licensing Another method to resolve FRAND disputes at the SSO level and through the ICT industry players’ voluntary collaboration is to utilize arbitration as proposed by Lemley and Shapiro.78 The arbitration approach to FRAND licensing is to adopt the negotiation scheme of traditional baseball-style arbitration. In the baseball-style arbitration, each party proposes a reasonable licensing royalty and the arbitrator choose one. To make the arbitration binding, the arbitration clause can be included in the IPR policies of SSOs that a patentee of SEPs should agree to. In the case of unwilling licensee, the patentee can sue for monetary damages and injunctive relief. 77 Almost all patents are filed during the standardization process, and thus, they will still be in pending and their claims can be changed log time after final approval of a standard. 78 Mark A. Lemley & Carl Shapiro, A Simple Approach to Setting Reasonable Royalties for Standard-Essential Patents (Stanford Public Law Working Paper No. 2243026 , 2013), available at http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=2243026.
  • 26. 26 The main advantage of this approach for FRAND licensing is its simplicity and efficiency for the determination of the royalty. The main drawback of this approach for FRAND licensing is to establish expertise and authority of the arbitrator by which not only the parties of the license but courts honor his or her decision.79 IV. Recommendations A. FRAND Royalty and Injunctive Relief Hybrid approach to FRAND royalty As can be seen in the previous discussion, there is no consensus among the ICT industry players to accept either the traditional entire product or rather the smallest saleable component, as FRAND royalty base. A method to resolve disagreement about FRAND royalty base may be a hybrid approach to royalty base that was suggested by the 3G licensing platform.80 The 3G licensing platform, which is the licensing organization for 3G mobile SEPs, adopted reference market value of the entire product as a royalty base, if the product consists of several functional blocks. For example, if the product performs 3G mobile communication and other functions that give values to the users of the product, the royalty base only take into account the value proportional to the 3G mobile communication function embedded in the entire product. Thus, if a mobile phone of price T includes a component of price A for mobile communication function 79 The court can refuse to recognize or enforce an arbitration award (i.e., the decision of an arbitrator) only under limited circumstances provided in the New York Convention, such as “against public policy.” The Convention is available at: http://www.uncitral.org/uncitral/uncitral_texts/arbitration/NYConvention.html. 80 Larry Goldstein & Brian Kearsey, Technology Patent Licensing 154 (Aspatore Books 2004).
  • 27. 27 and other components of price B for other independent functions and multiple components of price C for common functions supporting both mobile communication function and other independent functions, FRAND royalty base for mobile communication is A in the smallest saleable component approach and T in the entire market approach. In the hybrid approach to FRAND royalty, however, FRAND royalty base for mobile communication is A + C x [A/(A+B)] taking into account the net contribution of the multiple components for common functions to mobile communication. Consequently, FRAND royalty base is a compromise value between the two extremes such that it is the entire product value including only the smallest saleable function contributed by the patented feature of a SEP. Ex Post Pseudo-pool Approach The main concept of the ex post pseudo-pool approach to FRAND licensing is to set the total royalty that the implementers should pay independent of the number of SEPs for a given standard, which was the main advantage of the ex ante pseudo-pool approach. The patentees of SEPs for a given standard may form the ex post pseudo-pool to set the total royalty. The difference from the traditional patent pools is that the ex post pseudo-pool does not administrate the licensing processes. The ex post pseudo-pool can also evaluate whether the patentees’ SEPs are truly the SEPs through an authorized third-party agency or experts. Then, each participating members of the ex post pseudo-pool can receive a share of the FRAND royalty proportional to the number of true SEPs. Law and economic analysis for injunctive relief
  • 28. 28 It would be valuable to study the adequate compensation and availability of the injunctive relief for SEPs at the fundamental level beyond courts’ interpretations based on contractual obligation of FRAND commitments.81 The fundamental goal of providing certain exclusive rights for a limited time to one’s invention is to create incentives which can maximize social welfare (the difference between the economic benefits and costs) provided by the patent system. The economic benefits of the patent system are well described in the justification theories for the patent system.82 The most familiar justification of the patents system is that the patent system encourages useful inventions to society by providing patent rights as an incentive. The presumption of this justification is that motivating useful inventions always serve society beneficially and there would be no inventions without the patent system. Therefore, under this justification of the patent system, stronger the patent protection the more useful inventions will result in. This justification is called ex ante justification of the patent system because it focuses on the role of the patent system before the creation of inventions.83 The next justification of patent system is that the patent system induces commercial exploitation of inventions.84 The rational of this justification is that, absent patent protection, inventions would not be commercially exploited further due to fear of free ride on the inventions. Thus, under this justification of the patent system, exclusive rights, like the real property rights, are necessary to promote efficient use of inventions for maximizing the social welfares. 81 Apple, Inc. v. Motorola, Inc., No. 1:11-cv-08540 (N.D. Ill. 2012); Microsoft Co., v. Motorola, Inc., No. 2:10-cv- 01823-JLR (W.D. WA 2012). 82 See, e.g., The Patent Prospector, Patent Economics, http://www.patenthawk.com/blog/2005/04/patent_economics_part_4_incent.html (last visited Oct. 1, 2013). 83 Mark Lemley, ‘Ex Ante Versus Ex Post Justifications for Intellectual Property,’ 71 U. Chi L. Rev. 129 (2004). 84 Id.
  • 29. 29 Therefore, a case study for social welfare provided by SEPs85 taking into accounts the benefit provided by interoperability and the cost provided by the strong patent protections would provide another insight for the adequate compensation and availability of the injunctive relief for SEPs. B. Alternative Methods for FRAND Licensing Collaboration between SSOs and patent offices for ex ante FRAND licensing As an alternative method to resolve FRAND disputes, ex ante FRAND licensing at the SSO level by adapting IPR policies of SSOs was proposed. By the ex ante FRAND licensing, FRAND royalty can exclude the ex post hold up value that SEPs acquired after a standardized technology was adopted widely in the relevant technology market. The main drawback of this approach for FRAND licensing is the determination of SEPs because a patent office cannot grant most of candidates for SEPs upon final approval of a standard. A possible solution to this drawback would be the collaboration between SSOs and patent offices for ex ante granting of patents filed by the participating members of SSOs cover the standardized technology through an accelerated patent prosecution in the patent offices. 86 For example, IPR policies of SSOs can include a clause for the requirement of accelerated patent prosecution of patents relate to any proposal submitted during the 85 A good example for the case study will be the 3G mobile communications because there are enough information for empirical analysis. 86 Ex ante granting of SEPs would be possible utilizing the existing accelerated patent prosecution program in the patent offices. For example, USPTO operates the expedited examination of patent applications such as Prioritized Examination and Accelerated Examination.
  • 30. 30 standardization. Additionally, a SSO and a patent office can make an agreement for collaboration regarding accelerated patent prosecution of SEP candidate applications. Establishment of international arbitration agency for FRAND disputes resolution As another alternative method to resolve FRAND disputes, arbitration approach to FRAND licensing through ICT industry players’ voluntary collaboration was proposed. By the arbitration approach to FRAND licensing, FRAND royalty can be proposed by both parties in licensing agreement. The main drawback of this approach for FRAND disputes resolution is to establish expertise and authority of the arbitrator. A possible solution to this drawback would be the collaboration between SSOs and other international authorities. For example, World Intellectual Property Organization (WIPO) can be a good candidate for the collaboration because WIPO can select qualified arbitrators and train them for FRAND disputes resolution.87 Furthermore, WIPO could provide guidelines for evaluating essentiality of SEPs and reasonable royalty for FRAND licensing. Specifying WIPO as the authorized arbitration agency in the arbitration clause that is included in the IPR policies of SSOs can make patentees of SEPs subject to arbitration in WIPO in case there is any dispute concerning FRAND commitments. Still, this method, however, does not solve the issue completely because implementers of SEPs who are not the member of an SSO cannot be make bind the implementers to the arbitration in WIPO. Thus, it may be necessary to include a special clause that FRAND commitments and obligation of arbitration in WIPO only applied when implementers of SEPs agree to resolve any FRAND disputes through arbitration. 87 WIPO can utilize WIPO’s Arbitration and Mediation Center.
  • 31. 31 It would also be valuable to study the possibility of inclusion of relevant provisions regarding FRAND disputes resolution in the Agreement on Trade-Related Aspects of Intellectual Property Rights (TRIPS Agreement) like provisions on compulsory licenses of patents.88 V. Conclusion In this article, I presented the background of Smartphone Patent Wars and FRAND disputes surrounding SEPs among ICT industry incumbents. FRAND disputes involve directly concerned industry parties, public policy agencies, and courts. I reviewed in details courts resolutions, policy measures by regulation agencies, and industry parties’ response regarding interpretation of FRAND commitments, adequate remedy, availability of injunctive relief for SEPs, determination of FRAND Royalty, and antitrust matters. I also discussed potential adverse effects of courts’ resolutions to the ICT industry and alternative methods to resolve FRAND Disputes at the SSO level and through voluntary collaboration among ICT industry players. Considering the increasing disputes regarding SEPs in ICT industry, SSOs, courts, and regulatory agencies should make more efforts to resolve FRAND disputes. I have tried to provide a little contribution to the efforts of resolving FRAND disputes through recommendations and suggestions for further studies. 88 Article 31 of the TRIPS Agreement specifies the compulsory licenses of patents.