SlideShare a Scribd company logo
1 of 119
A Lesson on Elementary, Worldly Wisdom As It Relates To
Investment
Management & Business
Charles Munger, USC Business School, 1994
I'm going to play a minor trick on you today because the subject
of my talk is the art
of stock picking as a subdivision of the art of worldly wisdom.
That enables me to
start talking about worldly wisdom—a much broader topic that
interests me because I
think all too little of it is delivered by modern educational
systems, at least in an
effective way.
And therefore, the talk is sort of along the lines that some
behaviorist psychologists
call Grandma's rule after the wisdom of Grandma when she said
that you have to eat
the carrots before you get the dessert.
The carrot part of this talk is about the general subject of
worldly wisdom which is a
pretty good way to start. After all, the theory of modern
education is that you need a
general education before you specialize. And I think to some
extent, before you're
going to be a great stock picker, you need some general
education.
So, emphasizing what I sometimes waggishly call remedial
worldly wisdom, I'm going
to start by waltzing you through a few basic notions.
What is elementary, worldly wisdom? Well, the first rule is that
you can't really know
anything if you just remember isolated facts and try and bang
'em back. If the facts
don't hang together on a latticework of theory, you don't have
them in a usable form.
You've got to have models in your head. And you've got to array
your
experience—both vicarious and direct—on this latticework of
models. You may have
noticed students who just try to remember and pound back what
is remembered.
Well, they fail in school and in life. You've got to hang
experience on a latticework of
models in your head.
What are the models? Well, the first rule is that you've got to
have multiple models
—because if you just have one or two that you're using, the
nature of human
psychology is such that you'll torture reality so that it fits your
models, or at least
you'll think it does. You become the equivalent of a
chiropractor who, of course, is the
great boob in medicine.
It's like the old saying, "To the man with only a hammer, every
problem looks like a
nail." And of course, that's the way the chiropractor goes about
practicing medicine.
But that's a perfectly disastrous way to think and a perfectly
disastrous way to
operate in the world. So you've got to have multiple models.
And the models have to come from multiple disciplines—
because all the wisdom of the
world is not to be found in one little academic department.
That's why poetry
professors, by and large, are so unwise in a worldly sense. They
don't have enough
models in their heads. So you've got to have models across a
fair array of disciplines.
You may say, "My God, this is already getting way too tough."
But, fortunately, it isn't
that tough—because 80 or 90 important models will carry about
90% of the freight in
making you a worldly-wise person. And, of those, only a mere
handful really carry
very heavy freight.
So let's briefly review what kind of models and techniques
constitute this basic
knowledge that everybody has to have before they proceed to
being really good at a
narrow art like stock picking.
First there's mathematics. Obviously, you've got to be able to
handle numbers and
quantities—basic arithmetic. And the great useful model, after
compound interest, is
the elementary math of permutations and combinations. And
that was taught in my
Y Combinator: Elementary Worldly Wisdom
http://ycombinator.com/munger.html
1 of 22 9/18/2012 5:17 PM
bengbengbb
Highlight
bengbengbb
Highlight
bengbengbb
Highlight
bengbengbb
Highlight
bengbengbb
Highlight
day in the sophomore year in high school. I suppose by now in
great private schools,
it's probably down to the eighth grade or so.
It's very simple algebra. It was all worked out in the course of
about one year
between Pascal and Fermat. They worked it out casually in a
series of letters.
It's not that hard to learn. What is hard is to get so you use it
routinely almost
everyday of your life. The Fermat/Pascal system is dramatically
consonant with the
way that the world works. And it's fundamental truth. So you
simply have to have the
technique.
Many educational institutions—although not nearly enough—
have realized this. At
Harvard Business School, the great quantitative thing that bonds
the first-year class
together is what they call decision tree theory. All they do is
take high school algebra
and apply it to real life problems. And the students love it.
They're amazed to find
that high school algebra works in life....
By and large, as it works out, people can't naturally and
automatically do this. If you
understand elementary psychology, the reason they can't is
really quite simple: The
basic neural network of the brain is there through broad genetic
and cultural
evolution. And it's not Fermat/Pascal. It uses a very crude,
shortcut-type of
approximation. It's got elements of Fermat/Pascal in it.
However, it's not good.
So you have to learn in a very usable way this very elementary
math and use it
routinely in life—just the way if you want to become a golfer,
you can't use the
natural swing that broad evolution gave you. You have to
learn—to have a certain grip
and swing in a different way to realize your full potential as a
golfer.
If you don't get this elementary, but mildly unnatural,
mathematics of elementary
probability into your repertoire, then you go through a long life
like a onelegged man
in an asskicking contest. You're giving a huge advantage to
everybody else.
One of the advantages of a fellow like Buffett, whom I've
worked with all these years,
is that he automatically thinks in terms of decision trees and the
elementary math of
permutations and combinations....
Obviously, you have to know accounting. It's the language of
practical business life. It
was a very useful thing to deliver to civilization. I've heard it
came to civilization
through Venice which of course was once the great commercial
power in the
Mediterranean. However, double-entry bookkeeping was a hell
of an invention.
And it's not that hard to understand.
But you have to know enough about it to understand its
limitations—because although
accounting is the starting place, it's only a crude approximation.
And it's not very hard
to understand its limitations. For example, everyone can see that
you have to more or
less just guess at the useful life of a jet airplane or anything like
that. Just because
you express the depreciation rate in neat numbers doesn't make
it anything you really
know.
In terms of the limitations of accounting, one of my favorite
stories involves a very
great businessman named Carl Braun who created the CF Braun
Engineering
Company. It designed and built oil refineries—which is very
hard to do. And Braun
would get them to come in on time and not blow up and have
efficiencies and so
forth. This is a major art.
And Braun, being the thorough Teutonic type that he was, had a
number of quirks.
And one of them was that he took a look at standard accounting
and the way it was
applied to building oil refineries and he said, "This is asinine."
So he threw all of his accountants out and he took his engineers
and said, "Now, we'll
Y Combinator: Elementary Worldly Wisdom
http://ycombinator.com/munger.html
2 of 22 9/18/2012 5:17 PM
bengbengbb
Highlight
bengbengbb
Highlight
bengbengbb
Highlight
bengbengbb
Highlight
devise our own system of accounting to handle this process."
And in due time,
accounting adopted a lot of Carl Braun's notions. So he was a
formidably willful and
talented man who demonstrated both the importance of
accounting and the
importance of knowing its limitations.
He had another rule, from psychology, which, if you're
interested in wisdom, ought to
be part of your repertoire—like the elementary mathematics of
permutations and
combinations.
His rule for all the Braun Company's communications was
called the five W's—you had
to tell who was going to do what, where, when and why. And if
you wrote a letter or
directive in the Braun Company telling somebody to do
something, and you didn't tell
him why, you could get fired. In fact, you would get fired if you
did it twice.
You might ask why that is so important? Well, again that's a
rule of psychology. Just
as you think better if you array knowledge on a bunch of models
that are basically
answers to the question, why, why, why, if you always tell
people why, they'll
understand it better, they'll consider it more important, and
they'll be more likely to
comply. Even if they don't understand your reason, they'll be
more likely to comply.
So there's an iron rule that just as you want to start getting
worldly wisdom by asking
why, why, why, in communicating with other people about
everything, you want to
include why, why, why. Even if it's obvious, it's wise to stick in
the why.
Which models are the most reliable? Well, obviously, the
models that come from hard
science and engineering are the most reliable models on this
Earth. And engineering
quality control—at least the guts of it that matters to you and
me and people who are
not professional engineers—is very much based on the
elementary mathematics of
Fermat and Pascal:
It costs so much and you get so much less likelihood of it
breaking if you spend this
much. It's all elementary high school mathematics. And an
elaboration of that is what
Deming brought to Japan for all of that quality control stuff.
I don't think it's necessary for most people to be terribly facile
in statistics. For
example, I'm not sure that I can even pronounce the Poisson
distribution. But I know
what a Gaussian or normal distribution looks like and I know
that events and huge
aspects of reality end up distributed that way. So I can do a
rough calculation.
But if you ask me to work out something involving a Gaussian
distribution to ten
decimal points, I can't sit down and do the math. I'm like a
poker player who's
learned to play pretty well without mastering Pascal.
And by the way, that works well enough. But you have to
understand that bellshaped
curve at least roughly as well as I do.
And, of course, the engineering idea of a backup system is a
very powerful idea. The
engineering idea of breakpoints—that's a very powerful model,
too. The notion of a
critical mass—that comes out of physics—is a very powerful
model.
All of these things have great utility in looking at ordinary
reality. And all of this
cost-benefit analysis—hell, that's all elementary high school
algebra, too. It's just
been dolled up a little bit with fancy lingo.
I suppose the next most reliable models are from biology/
physiology because, after
all, all of us are programmed by our genetic makeup to be much
the same.
And then when you get into psychology, of course, it gets very
much more
complicated. But it's an ungodly important subject if you're
going to have any worldly
wisdom.
Y Combinator: Elementary Worldly Wisdom
http://ycombinator.com/munger.html
3 of 22 9/18/2012 5:17 PM
bengbengbb
Highlight
bengbengbb
Highlight
bengbengbb
Highlight
And you can demonstrate that point quite simply: There's not a
person in this room
viewing the work of a very ordinary professional magician who
doesn't see a lot of
things happening that aren't happening and not see a lot of
things happening that are
happening.
And the reason why is that the perceptual apparatus of man has
shortcuts in it. The
brain cannot have unlimited circuitry. So someone who knows
how to take advantage
of those shortcuts and cause the brain to miscalculate in certain
ways can cause you
to see things that aren't there.
Now you get into the cognitive function as distinguished from
the perceptual function.
And there, you are equally—more than equally in fact—likely to
be misled. Again, your
brain has a shortage of circuitry and so forth—and it's taking all
kinds of little
automatic shortcuts.
So when circumstances combine in certain ways—or more
commonly, your fellow man
starts acting like the magician and manipulates you on purpose
by causing your
cognitive dysfunction—you're a patsy.
And so just as a man working with a tool has to know its
limitations, a man working
with his cognitive apparatus has to know its limitations. And
this knowledge, by the
way, can be used to control and motivate other people....
So the most useful and practical part of psychology—which I
personally think can be
taught to any intelligent person in a week—is ungodly
important. And nobody taught
it to me by the way. I had to learn it later in life, one piece at a
time. And it was fairly
laborious. It's so elementary though that, when it was all over, I
felt like a fool.
And yeah, I'd been educated at Cal Tech and the Harvard Law
School and so forth. So
very eminent places miseducated people like you and me.
The elementary part of psychology—the psychology of
misjudgment, as I call it—is a
terribly important thing to learn. There are about 20 little
principles. And they
interact, so it gets slightly complicated. But the guts of it is
unbelievably important.
Terribly smart people make totally bonkers mistakes by failing
to pay heed to it. In
fact, I've done it several times during the last two or three years
in a very important
way. You never get totally over making silly mistakes.
There's another saying that comes from Pascal which I've
always considered one of
the really accurate observations in the history of thought. Pascal
said in essence, "The
mind of man at one and the same time is both the glory and the
shame of the
universe."
And that's exactly right. It has this enormous power. However,
it also has these
standard misfunctions that often cause it to reach wrong
conclusions. It also makes
man extraordinarily subject to manipulation by others. For
example, roughly half of
the army of Adolf Hitler was composed of believing Catholics.
Given enough clever
psychological manipulation, what human beings will do is quite
interesting.
Personally, I've gotten so that I now use a kind of two-track
analysis. First, what are
the factors that really govern the interests involved, rationally
considered? And
second, what are the subconscious influences where the brain at
a subconscious level
is automatically doing these things—which by and large are
useful, but which often
misfunction.
One approach is rationality—the way you'd work out a bridge
problem: by evaluating
the real interests, the real probabilities and so forth. And the
other is to evaluate the
psychological factors that cause subconscious conclusions—
many of which are wrong.
Y Combinator: Elementary Worldly Wisdom
http://ycombinator.com/munger.html
4 of 22 9/18/2012 5:17 PM
ye
Pencil
ye
Typewritten Text
Stop Here
ye
Typewritten Text
bengbengbb
Highlight
bengbengbb
Highlight
bengbengbb
Highlight
bengbengbb
Highlight
bengbengbb
Highlight
bengbengbb
Highlight
Now we come to another somewhat less reliable form of human
wisdom
—microeconomics. And here, I find it quite useful to think of a
free market
economy—or partly free market economy—as sort of the
equivalent of an
ecosystem....
This is a very unfashionable way of thinking because early in
the days after Darwin
came along, people like the robber barons assumed that the
doctrine of the survival of
the fittest authenticated them as deserving power—you know,
"I'm the richest.
Therefore, I'm the best. God's in his heaven, etc."
And that reaction of the robber barons was so irritating to
people that it made it
unfashionable to think of an economy as an ecosystem. But the
truth is that it is a lot
like an ecosystem. And you get many of the same results.
Just as in an ecosystem, people who narrowly specialize can get
terribly good at
occupying some little niche. Just as animals flourish in niches,
similarly, people who
specialize in the business world—and get very good because
they specialize
—frequently find good economics that they wouldn't get any
other way.
And once we get into microeconomics, we get into the concept
of advantages of scale.
Now we're getting closer to investment analysis—because in
terms of which
businesses succeed and which businesses fail, advantages of
scale are ungodly
important.
For example, one great advantage of scale taught in all of the
business schools of the
world is cost reductions along the so-called experience curve.
Just doing something
complicated in more and more volume enables human beings,
who are trying to
improve and are motivated by the incentives of capitalism, to do
it more and more
efficiently.
The very nature of things is that if you get a whole lot of
volume through your joint,
you get better at processing that volume. That's an enormous
advantage. And it has a
lot to do with which businesses succeed and fail....
Let's go through a list—albeit an incomplete one—of possible
advantages of scale.
Some come from simple geometry. If you're building a great
spherical tank, obviously
as you build it bigger, the amount of steel you use in the surface
goes up with the
square and the cubic volume goes up with the cube. So as you
increase the
dimensions, you can hold a lot more volume per unit area of
steel.
And there are all kinds of things like that where the simple
geometry—the simple
reality—gives you an advantage of scale.
For example, you can get advantages of scale from TV
advertising. When TV
advertising first arrived—when talking color pictures first came
into our living
rooms—it was an unbelievably powerful thing. And in the early
days, we had three
networks that had whatever it was—say 90% of the audience.
Well, if you were Procter & Gamble, you could afford to use
this new method of
advertising. You could afford the very expensive cost of
network television because
you were selling so many cans and bottles. Some little guy
couldn't. And there was no
way of buying it in part. Therefore, he couldn't use it. In effect,
if you didn't have a
big volume, you couldn't use network TV advertising which was
the most effective
technique.
So when TV came in, the branded companies that were already
big got a huge tail
wind. Indeed, they prospered and prospered and prospered until
some of them got fat
and foolish, which happens with prosperity—at least to some
people....
And your advantage of scale can be an informational advantage.
If I go to some
Y Combinator: Elementary Worldly Wisdom
http://ycombinator.com/munger.html
5 of 22 9/18/2012 5:17 PM
remote place, I may see Wrigley chewing gum alongside Glotz's
chewing gum. Well, I
know that Wrigley is a satisfactory product, whereas I don't
know anything about
Glotz's. So if one is 40 cents and the other is 30 cents, am I
going to take something I
don't know and put it in my mouth—which is a pretty personal
place, after all—for a
lousy dime?
So, in effect, Wrigley , simply by being so well known, has
advantages of scale—what
you might call an informational advantage.
Another advantage of scale comes from psychology. The
psychologists use the term
social proof. We are all influenced—subconsciously and to
some extent
consciously—by what we see others do and approve. Therefore,
if everybody's buying
something, we think it's better. We don't like to be the one guy
who's out of step.
Again, some of this is at a subconscious level and some of it
isn't. Sometimes, we
consciously and rationally think, "Gee, I don't know much about
this. They know more
than I do. Therefore, why shouldn't I follow them?"
The social proof phenomenon which comes right out of
psychology gives huge
advantages to scale—for example, with very wide distribution,
which of course is hard
to get. One advantage of Coca-Cola is that it's available almost
everywhere in the
world.
Well, suppose you have a little soft drink. Exactly how do you
make it available all
over the Earth? The worldwide distribution setup—which is
slowly won by a big
enterprise—gets to be a huge advantage.... And if you think
about it, once you get
enough advantages of that type, it can become very hard for
anybody to dislodge
you.
There's another kind of advantage to scale. In some businesses,
the very nature of
things is to sort of cascade toward the overwhelming dominance
of one firm.
The most obvious one is daily newspapers. There's practically
no city left in the U.S.,
aside from a few very big ones, where there's more than one
daily newspaper.
And again, that's a scale thing. Once I get most of the
circulation, I get most of the
advertising. And once I get most of the advertising and
circulation, why would anyone
want the thinner paper with less information in it? So it tends to
cascade to a
winnertakeall situation. And that's a separate form of the
advantages of scale
phenomenon.
Similarly, all these huge advantages of scale allow greater
specialization within the
firm. Therefore, each person can be better at what he does.
And these advantages of scale are so great, for example, that
when Jack Welch came
into General Electric, he just said, "To hell with it. We're either
going to be # 1 or #2
in every field we're in or we're going to be out. I don't care how
many people I have
to fire and what I have to sell. We're going to be #1 or #2 or
out."
That was a very toughminded thing to do, but I think it was a
very correct decision if
you're thinking about maximizing shareholder wealth. And I
don't think it's a bad
thing to do for a civilization either, because I think that General
Electric is stronger for
having Jack Welch there.
And there are also disadvantages of scale. For example, we—by
which I mean
Berkshire Hathaway—are the largest shareholder in Capital
Cities/ABC. And we had
trade publications there that got murdered where our
competitors beat us. And the
way they beat us was by going to a narrower specialization.
We'd have a travel magazine for business travel. So somebody
would create one
which was addressed solely at corporate travel departments.
Like an ecosystem,
Y Combinator: Elementary Worldly Wisdom
http://ycombinator.com/munger.html
6 of 22 9/18/2012 5:17 PM
you're getting a narrower and narrower specialization.
Well, they got much more efficient. They could tell more to the
guys who ran
corporate travel departments. Plus, they didn't have to waste the
ink and paper
mailing out stuff that corporate travel departments weren't
interested in reading. It
was a more efficient system. And they beat our brains out as we
relied on our broader
magazine.
That's what happened to The Saturday Evening Post and all
those things. They're
gone. What we have now is Motocross—which is read by a
bunch of nuts who like to
participate in tournaments where they turn somersaults on their
motorcycles. But
they care about it. For them, it's the principal purpose of life. A
magazine called
Motocross is a total necessity to those people. And its profit
margins would make you
salivate.
Just think of how narrowcast that kind of publishing is. So
occasionally, scaling down
and intensifying gives you the big advantage. Bigger is not
always better.
The great defect of scale, of course, which makes the game
interesting—so that the
big people don't always win—is that as you get big, you get the
bureaucracy. And with
the bureaucracy comes the territoriality—which is again
grounded in human nature.
And the incentives are perverse. For example, if you worked for
AT&T in my day, it
was a great bureaucracy. Who in the hell was really thinking
about the shareholder or
anything else? And in a bureaucracy, you think the work is done
when it goes out of
your in-basket into somebody else's in-basket. But, of course, it
isn't. It's not done
until AT&T delivers what it's supposed to deliver. So you get
big, fat, dumb,
unmotivated bureaucracies.
They also tend to become somewhat corrupt. In other words, if
I've got a department
and you've got a department and we kind of share power
running this thing, there's
sort of an unwritten rule: "If you won't bother me, I won't
bother you and we're both
happy." So you get layers of management and associated costs
that nobody needs.
Then, while people are justifying all these layers, it takes
forever to get anything
done. They're too slow to make decisions and nimbler people
run circles around them.
The constant curse of scale is that it leads to big, dumb
bureaucracy—which, of
course, reaches its highest and worst form in government where
the incentives are
really awful. That doesn't mean we don't need governments—
because we do. But it's
a terrible problem to get big bureaucracies to behave.
So people go to stratagems. They create little decentralized
units and fancy
motivation and training programs. For example, for a big
company, General Electric
has fought bureaucracy with amazing skill. But that's because
they have a
combination of a genius and a fanatic running it. And they put
him in young enough
so he gets a long run. Of course, that's Jack Welch.
But bureaucracy is terrible.... And as things get very powerful
and very big, you can
get some really dysfunctional behavior. Look at Westinghouse.
They blew billions of
dollars on a bunch of dumb loans to real estate developers. They
put some guy who'd
come up by some career path—I don't know exactly what it was,
but it could have
been refrigerators or something—and all of a sudden, he's
loaning money to real
estate developers building hotels. It's a very unequal contest.
And in due time, they
lost all those billions of dollars.
CBS provides an interesting example of another rule of
psychology—namely,
Pavlovian association. If people tell you what you really don't
want to hear what's
unpleasant—there's an almost automatic reaction of antipathy.
You have to train
yourself out of it. It isn't foredestined that you have to be this
way. But you will tend
to be this way if you don't think about it.
Y Combinator: Elementary Worldly Wisdom
http://ycombinator.com/munger.html
7 of 22 9/18/2012 5:17 PM
Television was dominated by one network—CBS in its early
days. And Paley was a
god. But he didn't like to hear what he didn't like to hear. And
people soon learned
that. So they told Paley only what he liked to hear. Therefore,
he was soon living in a
little cocoon of unreality and everything else was corrupt—
although it was a great
business.
So the idiocy that crept into the system was carried along by
this huge tide. It was a
Mad Hatter's tea party the last ten years under Bill Paley.
And that is not the only example by any means. You can get
severe misfunction in the
high ranks of business. And of course, if you're investing, it can
make a lot of
difference. If you take all the acquisitions that CBS made under
Paley, after the
acquisition of the network itself, with all his advisors—his
investment bankers,
management consultants and so forth who were getting paid
very handsomely—it was
absolutely terrible.
For example, he gave something like 20% of CBS to the
Dumont Company for a
television set manufacturer which was destined to go broke. I
think it lasted all of two
or three years or something like that. So very soon after he'd
issued all of that stock,
Dumont was history. You get a lot of dysfunction in a big fat,
powerful place where no
one will bring unwelcome reality to the boss.
So life is an everlasting battle between those two forces—to get
these advantages of
scale on one side and a tendency to get a lot like the U.S.
Agriculture Department on
the other side—where they just sit around and so forth. I don't
know exactly what
they do. However, I do know that they do very little useful
work.
On the subject of advantages of economies of scale, I find chain
stores quite
interesting. Just think about it. The concept of a chain store was
a fascinating
invention. You get this huge purchasing power—which means
that you have lower
merchandise costs. You get a whole bunch of little laboratories
out there in which you
can conduct experiments. And you get specialization.
If one little guy is trying to buy across 27 different merchandise
categories influenced
by traveling salesmen, he's going to make a lot of poor
decisions. But if your buying is
done in headquarters for a huge bunch of stores, you can get
very bright people that
know a lot about refrigerators and so forth to do the buying.
The reverse is demonstrated by the little store where one guy is
doing all the buying.
It's like the old story about the little store with salt all over its
walls. And a stranger
comes in and says to the storeowner, "You must sell a lot of
salt." And he replies, "No,
I don't. But you should see the guy who sells me salt."
So there are huge purchasing advantages. And then there are the
slick systems of
forcing everyone to do what works. So a chain store can be a
fantastic enterprise.
It's quite interesting to think about Wal-Mart starting from a
single store in
Bentonville, Arkansas against Sears, Roebuck with its name,
reputation and all of its
billions. How does a guy in Bentonville, Arkansas with no
money blow right by Sears,
Roebuck? And he does it in his own lifetime—in fact, during his
own late lifetime
because he was already pretty old by the time he started out
with one little store....
He played the chain store game harder and better than anyone
else. Walton invented
practically nothing. But he copied everything anybody else ever
did that was
smart—and he did it with more fanaticism and better employee
manipulation. So he
just blew right by them all.
He also had a very interesting competitive strategy in the early
days. He was like a
prizefighter who wanted a great record so he could be in the
finals and make a big TV
hit. So what did he do? He went out and fought 42 palookas.
Right? And the result
Y Combinator: Elementary Worldly Wisdom
http://ycombinator.com/munger.html
8 of 22 9/18/2012 5:17 PM
was knockout, knockout, knockout—42 times.
Walton, being as shrewd as he was, basically broke other small
town merchants in the
early days. With his more efficient system, he might not have
been able to tackle
some titan head-on at the time. But with his better system, he
could destroy those
small town merchants. And he went around doing it time after
time after time. Then,
as he got bigger, he started destroying the big boys.
Well, that was a very, very shrewd strategy.
You can say, "Is this a nice way to behave?" Well, capitalism is
a pretty brutal place.
But I personally think that the world is better for having Wal-
Mart. I mean you can
idealize small town life. But I've spent a fair amount of time in
small towns. And let
me tell you you shouldn't get too idealistic about all those
businesses he destroyed.
Plus, a lot of people who work at Wal-Mart are very high grade,
bouncy people who
are raising nice children. I have no feeling that an inferior
culture destroyed a superior
culture. I think that is nothing more than nostalgia and delusion.
But, at any rate, it's
an interesting model of how the scale of things and fanaticism
combine to be very
powerful.
And it's also an interesting model on the other side—how with
all its great
advantages, the disadvantages of bureaucracy did such terrible
damage to Sears,
Roebuck. Sears had layers and layers of people it didn't need. It
was very
bureaucratic. It was slow to think. And there was an established
way of thinking. If
you poked your head up with a new thought, the system kind of
turned against you. It
was everything in the way of a dysfunctional big bureaucracy
that you would expect.
In all fairness, there was also much that was good about it. But
it just wasn't as lean
and mean and shrewd and effective as Sam Walton. And, in due
time, all its
advantages of scale were not enough to prevent Sears from
losing heavily to Wal-Mart
and other similar retailers.
Here's a model that we've had trouble with. Maybe you'll be
able to figure it out
better. Many markets get down to two or three big
competitors—or five or six. And in
some of those markets, nobody makes any money to speak of.
But in others,
everybody does very well.
Over the years, we've tried to figure out why the competition in
some markets gets
sort of rational from the investor's point of view so that the
shareholders do well, and
in other markets, there's destructive competition that destroys
shareholder wealth.
If it's a pure commodity like airline seats, you can understand
why no one makes any
money. As we sit here, just think of what airlines have given to
the world—safe travel,
greater experience, time with your loved ones, you name it. Yet,
the net amount of
money that's been made by the shareholders of airlines since
Kitty Hawk, is now a
negative figure—a substantial negative figure. Competition was
so intense that, once
it was unleashed by deregulation, it ravaged shareholder wealth
in the airline
business.
Yet, in other fields—like cereals, for example—almost all the
big boys make out. If
you're some kind of a medium grade cereal maker, you might
make 15% on your
capital. And if you're really good, you might make 40%. But
why are cereals so
profitable—despite the fact that it looks to me like they're
competing like crazy with
promotions, coupons and everything else? I don't fully
understand it.
Obviously, there's a brand identity factor in cereals that doesn't
exist in airlines. That
must be the main factor that accounts for it.
And maybe the cereal makers by and large have learned to be
less crazy about
fighting for market share—because if you get even one person
who's hell-bent on
Y Combinator: Elementary Worldly Wisdom
http://ycombinator.com/munger.html
9 of 22 9/18/2012 5:17 PM
gaining market share.... For example, if I were Kellogg and I
decided that I had to
have 60% of the market, I think I could take most of the profit
out of cereals. I'd ruin
Kellogg in the process. But I think I could do it.
In some businesses, the participants behave like a demented
Kellogg. In other
businesses, they don't. Unfortunately, I do not have a perfect
model for predicting
how that's going to happen.
For example, if you look around at bottler markets, you'll find
many markets where
bottlers of Pepsi and Coke both make a lot of money and many
others where they
destroy most of the profitability of the two franchises. That
must get down to the
peculiarities of individual adjustment to market capitalism. I
think you'd have to know
the people involved to fully understand what was happening.
In microeconomics, of course, you've got the concept of patents,
trademarks,
exclusive franchises and so forth. Patents are quite interesting.
When I was young, I
think more money went into patents than came out. Judges
tended to throw them
out—based on arguments about what was really invented and
what relied on prior art.
That isn't altogether clear.
But they changed that. They didn't change the laws. They just
changed the
administration—so that it all goes to one patent court. And that
court is now very
much more pro-patent. So I think people are now starting to
make a lot of money out
of owning patents.
Trademarks, of course, have always made people a lot of
money. A trademark system
is a wonderful thing for a big operation if it's well known.
The exclusive franchise can also be wonderful. If there were
only three television
channels awarded in a big city and you owned one of them,
there were only so many
hours a day that you could be on. So you had a natural position
in an oligopoly in the
pre-cable days.
And if you get the franchise for the only food stand in an
airport, you have a captive
clientele and you have a small monopoly of a sort.
The great lesson in microeconomics is to discriminate between
when technology is
going to help you and when it's going to kill you. And most
people do not get this
straight in their heads. But a fellow like Buffett does.
For example, when we were in the textile business, which is a
terrible commodity
business, we were making low-end textiles—which are a real
commodity product. And
one day, the people came to Warren and said, "They've invented
a new loom that we
think will do twice as much work as our old ones."
And Warren said, "Gee, I hope this doesn't work because if it
does, I'm going to close
the mill." And he meant it.
What was he thinking? He was thinking, "It's a lousy business.
We're earning
substandard returns and keeping it open just to be nice to the
elderly workers. But
we're not going to put huge amounts of new capital into a lousy
business."
And he knew that the huge productivity increases that would
come from a better
machine introduced into the production of a commodity product
would all go to the
benefit of the buyers of the textiles. Nothing was going to stick
to our ribs as owners.
That's such an obvious concept—that there are all kinds of
wonderful new inventions
that give you nothing as owners except the opportunity to spend
a lot more money in
a business that's still going to be lousy. The money still won't
come to you. All of the
advantages from great improvements are going to flow through
to the customers.
Y Combinator: Elementary Worldly Wisdom
http://ycombinator.com/munger.html
10 of 22 9/18/2012 5:17 PM
Conversely, if you own the only newspaper in Oshkosh and they
were to invent more
efficient ways of composing the whole newspaper, then when
you got rid of the old
technology and got new fancy computers and so forth, all of the
savings would come
right through to the bottom line.
In all cases, the people who sell the machinery—and, by and
large, even the internal
bureaucrats urging you to buy the equipment—show you
projections with the amount
you'll save at current prices with the new technology. However,
they don't do the
second step of the analysis which is to determine how much is
going stay home and
how much is just going to flow through to the customer. I've
never seen a single
projection incorporating that second step in my life. And I see
them all the time.
Rather, they always read: "This capital outlay will save you so
much money that it will
pay for itself in three years."
So you keep buying things that will pay for themselves in three
years. And after 20
years of doing it, somehow you've earned a return of only about
4% per annum.
That's the textile business.
And it isn't that the machines weren't better. It's just that the
savings didn't go to
you. The cost reductions came through all right. But the benefit
of the cost reductions
didn't go to the guy who bought the equipment. It's such a
simple idea. It's so basic.
And yet it's so often forgotten.
Then there's another model from microeconomics which I find
very interesting. When
technology moves as fast as it does in a civilization like ours,
you get a phenomenon
which I call competitive destruction. You know, you have the
finest buggy whip
factory and all of a sudden in comes this little horseless
carriage. And before too
many years go by, your buggy whip business is dead. You either
get into a different
business or you're dead—you're destroyed. It happens again and
again and again.
And when these new businesses come in, there are huge
advantages for the early
birds. And when you're an early bird, there's a model that I call
"surfing"—when a
surfer gets up and catches the wave and just stays there, he can
go a long, long time.
But if he gets off the wave, he becomes mired in shallows....
But people get long runs when they're right on the edge of the
wave—whether it's
Microsoft or Intel or all kinds of people, including National
Cash Register in the early
days.
The cash register was one of the great contributions to
civilization. It's a wonderful
story. Patterson was a small retail merchant who didn't make
any money. One day,
somebody sold him a crude cash register which he put into his
retail operation. And it
instantly changed from losing money to earning a profit because
it made it so much
harder for the employees to steal....
But Patterson, having the kind of mind that he did, didn't think,
"Oh, good for my
retail business." He thought, "I'm going into the cash register
business." And, of
course, he created National Cash Register.
And he "surfed". He got the best distribution system, the
biggest collection of patents
and the best of everything. He was a fanatic about everything
important as the
technology developed. I have in my files an early National Cash
Register Company
report in which Patterson described his methods and objectives.
And a well-educated
orangutan could see that buying into partnership with Patterson
in those early days,
given his notions about the cash register business, was a total
100% cinch.
And, of course, that's exactly what an investor should be
looking for. In a long life,
you can expect to profit heavily from at least a few of those
opportunities if you
develop the wisdom and will to seize them. At any rate,
"surfing" is a very powerful
model.
Y Combinator: Elementary Worldly Wisdom
http://ycombinator.com/munger.html
11 of 22 9/18/2012 5:17 PM
However, Berkshire Hathaway , by and large, does not invest in
these people that are
"surfing" on complicated technology. After all, we're cranky
and idiosyncratic—as you
may have noticed.
And Warren and I don't feel like we have any great advantage in
the high-tech sector.
In fact, we feel like we're at a big disadvantage in trying to
understand the nature of
technical developments in software, computer chips or what
have you. So we tend to
avoid that stuff, based on our personal inadequacies.
Again, that is a very, very powerful idea. Every person is going
to have a circle of
competence. And it's going to be very hard to advance that
circle. If I had to make
my living as a musician.... I can't even think of a level low
enough to describe where I
would be sorted out to if music were the measuring standard of
the civilization.
So you have to figure out what your own aptitudes are. If you
play games where
other people have the aptitudes and you don't, you're going to
lose. And that's as
close to certain as any prediction that you can make. You have
to figure out where
you've got an edge. And you've got to play within your own
circle of competence.
If you want to be the best tennis player in the world, you may
start out trying and
soon find out that it's hopeless—that other people blow right by
you. However, if you
want to become the best plumbing contractor in Bemidji, that is
probably doable by
two-thirds of you. It takes a will. It takes the intelligence. But
after a while, you'd
gradually know all about the plumbing business in Bemidji and
master the art. That is
an attainable objective, given enough discipline. And people
who could never win a
chess tournament or stand in center court in a respectable tennis
tournament can rise
quite high in life by slowly developing a circle of competence—
which results partly
from what they were born with and partly from what they
slowly develop through
work.
So some edges can be acquired. And the game of life to some
extent for most of us is
trying to be something like a good plumbing contractor in
Bemidji. Very few of us are
chosen to win the world's chess tournaments.
Some of you may find opportunities "surfing" along in the new
high-tech fields—the
Intels, the Microsofts and so on. The fact that we don't think
we're very good at it and
have pretty well stayed out of it doesn't mean that it's irrational
for you to do it.
Well, so much for the basic microeconomics models, a little bit
of psychology, a little
bit of mathematics, helping create what I call the general
substructure of worldly
wisdom. Now, if you want to go on from carrots to dessert, I'll
turn to stock picking
—trying to draw on this general worldly wisdom as we go.
I don't want to get into emerging markets, bond arbitrage and so
forth. I'm talking
about nothing but plain vanilla stock picking. That, believe me,
is complicated enough.
And I'm talking about common stock picking.
The first question is, "What is the nature of the stock market?"
And that gets you
directly to this efficient market theory that got to be the rage—a
total rage—long after
I graduated from law school.
And it's rather interesting because one of the greatest
economists of the world is a
substantial shareholder in Berkshire Hathaway and has been for
a long time. His
textbook always taught that the stock market was perfectly
efficient and that nobody
could beat it. But his own money went into Berkshire and made
him wealthy. So, like
Pascal in his famous wager, he hedged his bet.
Is the stock market so efficient that people can't beat it? Well,
the efficient market
theory is obviously roughly right—meaning that markets are
quite efficient and it's
quite hard for anybody to beat the market by significant margins
as a stock picker by
Y Combinator: Elementary Worldly Wisdom
http://ycombinator.com/munger.html
12 of 22 9/18/2012 5:17 PM
just being intelligent and working in a disciplined way.
Indeed, the average result has to be the average result. By
definition, everybody can't
beat the market. As I always say, the iron rule of life is that
only 20% of the people
can be in the top fifth. That's just the way it is. So the answer is
that it's partly
efficient and partly inefficient.
And, by the way, I have a name for people who went to the
extreme efficient market
theory—which is "bonkers". It was an intellectually consistent
theory that enabled
them to do pretty mathematics. So I understand its
seductiveness to people with
large mathematical gifts. It just had a difficulty in that the
fundamental assumption
did not tie properly to reality.
Again, to the man with a hammer, every problem looks like a
nail. If you're good at
manipulating higher mathematics in a consistent way, why not
make an assumption
which enables you to use your tool?
The model I like—to sort of simplify the notion of what goes on
in a market for
common stocks—is the pari-mutuel system at the racetrack. If
you stop to think about
it, a pari-mutuel system is a market. Everybody goes there and
bets and the odds
change based on what's bet. That's what happens in the stock
market.
Any damn fool can see that a horse carrying a light weight with
a wonderful win rate
and a good post position etc., etc. is way more likely to win
than a horse with a
terrible record and extra weight and so on and so on. But if you
look at the odds, the
bad horse pays 100 to 1, whereas the good horse pays 3 to 2.
Then it's not clear
which is statistically the best bet using the mathematics of
Fermat and Pascal. The
prices have changed in such a way that it's very hard to beat the
system.
And then the track is taking 17% off the top. So not only do you
have to outwit all the
other betters, but you've got to outwit them by such a big
margin that on average,
you can afford to take 17% of your gross bets off the top and
give it to the house
before the rest of your money can be put to work.
Given those mathematics, is it possible to beat the horses only
using one's
intelligence? Intelligence should give some edge, because lots
of people who don't
know anything go out and bet lucky numbers and so forth.
Therefore, somebody who
really thinks about nothing but horse performance and is shrewd
and mathematical
could have a very considerable edge, in the absence of the
frictional cost caused by
the house take.
Unfortunately, what a shrewd horseplayer's edge does in most
cases is to reduce his
average loss over a season of betting from the 17% that he
would lose if he got the
average result to maybe 10%. However, there are actually a few
people who can beat
the game after paying the full 17%.
I used to play poker when I was young with a guy who made a
substantial living doing
nothing but bet harness races.... Now, harness racing is a
relatively inefficient market.
You don't have the depth of intelligence betting on harness
races that you do on
regular races. What my poker pal would do was to think about
harness races as his
main profession. And he would bet only occasionally when he
saw some mispriced bet
available. And by doing that, after paying the full handle to the
house—which I
presume was around 17%—he made a substantial living.
You have to say that's rare. However, the market was not
perfectly efficient. And if it
weren't for that big 17% handle, lots of people would regularly
be beating lots of
other people at the horse races. It's efficient, yes. But it's not
perfectly efficient. And
with enough shrewdness and fanaticism, some people will get
better results than
others.
The stock market is the same way—except that the house handle
is so much lower. If
Y Combinator: Elementary Worldly Wisdom
http://ycombinator.com/munger.html
13 of 22 9/18/2012 5:17 PM
ye
Pencil
you take transaction costs—the spread between the bid and the
ask plus the
commissions—and if you don't trade too actively, you're talking
about fairly low
transaction costs. So that with enough fanaticism and enough
discipline, some of the
shrewd people are going to get way better results than average
in the nature of
things.
It is not a bit easy. And, of course, 50% will end up in the
bottom half and 70% will
end up in the bottom 70%. But some people will have an
advantage. And in a fairly
low transaction cost operation, they will get better than average
results in stock
picking.
How do you get to be one of those who is a winner—in a
relative sense—instead of a
loser?
Here again, look at the pari-mutuel system. I had dinner last
night by absolute
accident with the president of Santa Anita. He says that there
are two or three betters
who have a credit arrangement with them, now that they have
off-track betting, who
are actually beating the house. They're sending money out net
after the full handle—a
lot of it to Las Vegas, by the way—to people who are actually
winning slightly, net,
after paying the full handle. They're that shrewd about
something with as much
unpredictability as horse racing.
And the one thing that all those winning betters in the whole
history of people who've
beaten the pari-mutuel system have is quite simple. They bet
very seldom.
It's not given to human beings to have such talent that they can
just know everything
about everything all the time. But it is given to human beings
who work hard at
it—who look and sift the world for a mispriced be—that they
can occasionally find one.
And the wise ones bet heavily when the world offers them that
opportunity. They bet
big when they have the odds. And the rest of the time, they
don't. It's just that
simple.
That is a very simple concept. And to me it's obviously right—
based on experience not
only from the pari-mutuel system, but everywhere else.
And yet, in investment management, practically nobody
operates that way. We
operate that way—I'm talking about Buffett and Munger. And
we're not alone in the
world. But a huge majority of people have some other crazy
construct in their heads.
And instead of waiting for a near cinch and loading up, they
apparently ascribe to the
theory that if they work a little harder or hire more business
school students, they'll
come to know everything about everything all the time.
To me, that's totally insane. The way to win is to work, work,
work, work and hope to
have a few insights.
How many insights do you need? Well, I'd argue: that you don't
need many in a
lifetime. If you look at Berkshire Hathaway and all of its
accumulated billions, the top
ten insights account for most of it. And that's with a very
brilliant man—Warren's a lot
more able than I am and very disciplined—devoting his lifetime
to it. I don't mean to
say that he's only had ten insights. I'm just saying, that most of
the money came
from ten insights.
So you can get very remarkable investment results if you think
more like a winning
pari-mutuel player. Just think of it as a heavy odds against game
full of craziness with
an occasional mispriced something or other. And you're
probably not going to be
smart enough to find thousands in a lifetime. And when you get
a few, you really load
up. It's just that simple.
When Warren lectures at business schools, he says, "I could
improve your ultimate
financial welfare by giving you a ticket with only 20 slots in it
so that you had 20
Y Combinator: Elementary Worldly Wisdom
http://ycombinator.com/munger.html
14 of 22 9/18/2012 5:17 PM
punches—representing all the investments that you got to make
in a lifetime. And
once you'd punched through the card, you couldn't make any
more investments at
all."
He says, "Under those rules, you'd really think carefully about
what you did and you'd
be forced to load up on what you'd really thought about. So
you'd do so much better."
Again, this is a concept that seems perfectly obvious to me. And
to Warren it seems
perfectly obvious. But this is one of the very few business
classes in the U.S. where
anybody will be saying so. It just isn't the conventional wisdom.
To me, it's obvious that the winner has to bet very selectively.
It's been obvious to me
since very early in life. I don't know why it's not obvious to
very many other people.
I think the reason why we got into such idiocy in investment
management is best
illustrated by a story that I tell about the guy who sold fishing
tackle. I asked him,
"My God, they're purple and green. Do fish really take these
lures?" And he said,
"Mister, I don't sell to fish."
Investment managers are in the position of that fishing tackle
salesman. They're like
the guy who was selling salt to the guy who already had too
much salt. And as long as
the guy will buy salt, why they'll sell salt. But that isn't what
ordinarily works for the
buyer of investment advice.
If you invested Berkshire Hathaway-style, it would be hard to
get paid as an
investment manager as well as they're currently paid—because
you'd be holding a
block of Wal-Mart and a block of Coca-Cola and a block of
something else. You'd just
sit there. And the client would be getting rich. And, after a
while, the client would
think, "Why am I paying this guy half a percent a year on my
wonderful passive
holdings?"
So what makes sense for the investor is different from what
makes sense for the
manager. And, as usual in human affairs, what determines the
behavior are incentives
for the decision maker.
From all business, my favorite case on incentives is Federal
Express. The heart and
soul of their system—which creates the integrity of the
product—is having all their
airplanes come to one place in the middle of the night and shift
all the packages from
plane to plane. If there are delays, the whole operation can't
deliver a product full of
integrity to Federal Express customers.
And it was always screwed up. They could never get it done on
time. They tried
everything—moral suasion, threats, you name it. And nothing
worked.
Finally, somebody got the idea to pay all these people not so
much an hour, but so
much a shift—and when it's all done, they can all go home.
Well, their problems
cleared up overnight.
So getting the incentives right is a very, very important lesson.
It was not obvious to
Federal Express what the solution was. But maybe now, it will
hereafter more often be
obvious to you.
All right, we've now recognized that the market is efficient as a
pari-mutuel system is
efficient with the favorite more likely than the long shot to do
well in racing, but not
necessarily give any betting advantage to those that bet on the
favorite.
In the stock market, some railroad that's beset by better
competitors and tough
unions may be available at one-third of its book value. In
contrast, IBM in its heyday
might be selling at 6 times book value. So it's just like the pari-
mutuel system. Any
damn fool could plainly see that IBM had better business
prospects than the railroad.
But once you put the price into the formula, it wasn't so clear
anymore what was
Y Combinator: Elementary Worldly Wisdom
http://ycombinator.com/munger.html
15 of 22 9/18/2012 5:17 PM
ye
Pencil
ye
Typewritten Text
Stop Here
going to work best for a buyer choosing between the stocks. So
it's a lot like a
pari-mutuel system. And, therefore, it gets very hard to beat.
What style should the investor use as a picker of common stocks
in order to try to
beat the market—in other words, to get an above average long-
term result? A
standard technique that appeals to a lot of people is called
"sector rotation". You
simply figure out when oils are going to outperform retailers,
etc., etc., etc. You just
kind of flit around being in the hot sector of the market making
better choices than
other people. And presumably, over a long period of time, you
get ahead.
However, I know of no really rich sector rotator. Maybe some
people can do it. I'm not
saying they can't. All I know is that all the people I know who
got rich—and I know a
lot of them—did not do it that way.
The second basic approach is the one that Ben Graham used—
much admired by
Warren and me. As one factor, Graham had this concept of
value to a private
owner—what the whole enterprise would sell for if it were
available. And that was
calculable in many cases.
Then, if you could take the stock price and multiply it by the
number of shares and
get something that was one third or less of sellout value, he
would say that you've got
a lot of edge going for you. Even with an elderly alcoholic
running a stodgy business,
this significant excess of real value per share working for you
means that all kinds of
good things can happen to you. You had a huge margin of
safety—as he put it—by
having this big excess value going for you.
But he was, by and large, operating when the world was in shell
shock from the
1930s—which was the worst contraction in the English-
speaking world in about 600
years. Wheat in Liverpool, I believe, got down to something
like a 600-year low,
adjusted for inflation. People were so shell-shocked for a long
time thereafter that Ben
Graham could run his Geiger counter over this detritus from the
collapse of the 1930s
and find things selling below their working capital per share
and so on.
And in those days, working capital actually belonged to the
shareholders. If the
employees were no longer useful, you just sacked them all, took
the working capital
and stuck it in the owners' pockets. That was the way capitalism
then worked.
Nowadays, of course, the accounting is not realistic because the
minute the business
starts contracting, significant assets are not there. Under social
norms and the new
legal rules of the civilization, so much is owed to the employees
that, the minute the
enterprise goes into reverse, some of the assets on the balance
sheet aren't there
anymore.
Now, that might not be true if you run a little auto dealership
yourself. You may be
able to run it in such a way that there's no health plan and this
and that so that if the
business gets lousy, you can take your working capital and go
home. But IBM can't, or
at least didn't. Just look at what disappeared from its balance
sheet when it decided
that it had to change size both because the world had changed
technologically and
because its market position had deteriorated.
And in terms of blowing it, IBM is some example. Those were
brilliant, disciplined
people. But there was enough turmoil in technological change
that IBM got bounced
off the wave after "surfing" successfully for 60 years. And that
was some collapse—an
object lesson in the difficulties of technology and one of the
reasons why Buffett and
Munger don't like technology very much. We don't think we're
any good at it, and
strange things can happen.
At any rate, the trouble with what I call the classic Ben Graham
concept is that
gradually the world wised up and those real obvious bargains
disappeared. You could
run your Geiger counter over the rubble and it wouldn't click.
Y Combinator: Elementary Worldly Wisdom
http://ycombinator.com/munger.html
16 of 22 9/18/2012 5:17 PM
But such is the nature of people who have a hammer—to whom,
as I mentioned,
every problem looks like a nail that the Ben Graham followers
responded by changing
the calibration on their Geiger counters. In effect, they started
defining a bargain in a
different way. And they kept changing the definition so that
they could keep doing
what they'd always done. And it still worked pretty well. So the
Ben Graham
intellectual system was a very good one.
Of course, the best part of it all was his concept of "Mr.
Market". Instead of thinking
the market was efficient, he treated it as a manic-depressive
who comes by every
day. And some days he says, "I'll sell you some of my interest
for way less than you
think it's worth." And other days, "Mr. Market" comes by and
says, "I'll buy your
interest at a price that's way higher than you think it's worth."
And you get the option
of deciding whether you want to buy more, sell part of what you
already have or do
nothing at all.
To Graham, it was a blessing to be in business with a manic-
depressive who gave you
this series of options all the time. That was a very significant
mental construct. And
it's been very useful to Buffett, for instance, over his whole
adult lifetime.
However, if we'd stayed with classic Graham the way Ben
Graham did it, we would
never have had the record we have. And that's because Graham
wasn't trying to do
what we did.
For example, Graham didn't want to ever talk to management.
And his reason was
that, like the best sort of professor aiming his teaching at a
mass audience, he was
trying to invent a system that anybody could use. And he didn't
feel that the man in
the street could run around and talk to managements and learn
things. He also had a
concept that the management would often couch the information
very shrewdly to
mislead. Therefore, it was very difficult. And that is still true,
of course—human
nature being what it is.
And so having started out as Grahamites which, by the way,
worked fine—we
gradually got what I would call better insights. And we realized
that some company
that was selling at 2 or 3 times book value could still be a hell
of a bargain because of
momentums implicit in its position, sometimes combined with
an unusual managerial
skill plainly present in some individual or other, or some system
or other.
And once we'd gotten over the hurdle of recognizing that a thing
could be a bargain
based on quantitative measures that would have horrified
Graham, we started
thinking about better businesses.
And, by the way, the bulk of the billions in Berkshire Hathaway
have come from the
better businesses. Much of the first $200 or $300 million came
from scrambling
around with our Geiger counter. But the great bulk of the money
has come from the
great businesses.
And even some of the early money was made by being
temporarily present in great
businesses. Buffett Partnership, for example, owned American
Express and Disney
when they got pounded down.
Most investment managers are in a game where the clients
expect them to know a lot
about a lot of things. We didn't have any clients who could fire
us at Berkshire
Hathaway. So we didn't have to be governed by any such
construct. And we came to
this notion of finding a mispriced bet and loading up when we
were very confident
that we were right. So we're way less diversified. And I think
our system is miles
better.
However, in all fairness, I don't think a lot of money managers
could successfully sell
their services if they used our system. But if you're investing
for 40 years in some
pension fund, what difference does it make if the path from start
to finish is a little
Y Combinator: Elementary Worldly Wisdom
http://ycombinator.com/munger.html
17 of 22 9/18/2012 5:17 PM
more bumpy or a little different than everybody else's so long as
it's all going to work
out well in the end? So what if there's a little extra volatility.
In investment management today, everybody wants not only to
win, but to have a
yearly outcome path that never diverges very much from a
standard path except on
the upside. Well, that is a very artificial, crazy construct. That's
the equivalent in
investment management to the custom of binding the feet of
Chinese women. It's the
equivalent of what Nietzsche meant when he criticized the man
who had a lame leg
and was proud of it.
That is really hobbling yourself. Now, investment managers
would say, "We have to
be that way. That's how we're measured." And they may be right
in terms of the way
the business is now constructed. But from the viewpoint of a
rational consumer, the
whole system's "bonkers" and draws a lot of talented people
into socially useless
activity.
And the Berkshire system is not "bonkers". It's so damned
elementary that even
bright people are going to have limited, really valuable insights
in a very competitive
world when they're fighting against other very bright,
hardworking people.
And it makes sense to load up on the very few good insights you
have instead of
pretending to know everything about everything at all times.
You're much more likely
to do well if you start out to do something feasible instead of
something that isn't
feasible. Isn't that perfectly obvious?
How many of you have 56 brilliant ideas in which you have
equal confidence? Raise
your hands, please. How many of you have two or three insights
that you have some
confidence in? I rest my case.
I'd say that Berkshire Hathaway's system is adapting to the
nature of the investment
problem as it really is.
We've really made the money out of high quality businesses. In
some cases, we
bought the whole business. And in some cases, we just bought a
big block of stock.
But when you analyze what happened, the big money's been
made in the high quality
businesses. And most of the other people who've made a lot of
money have done so
in high quality businesses.
Over the long term, it's hard for a stock to earn a much better
return than the
business which underlies it earns. If the business earns 6% on
capital over 40 years
and you hold it for that 40 years, you're not going to make much
different than a 6%
return—even if you originally buy it at a huge discount.
Conversely, if a business
earns 18% on capital over 20 or 30 years, even if you pay an
expensive looking price,
you'll end up with a fine result.
So the trick is getting into better businesses. And that involves
all of these
advantages of scale that you could consider momentum effects.
How do you get into these great companies? One method is
what I'd call the method
of finding them small get 'em when they're little. For example,
buy Wal-Mart when
Sam Walton first goes public and so forth. And a lot of people
try to do just that. And
it's a very beguiling idea. If I were a young man, I might
actually go into it.
But it doesn't work for Berkshire Hathaway anymore because
we've got too much
money. We can't find anything that fits our size parameter that
way. Besides, we're
set in our ways. But I regard finding them small as a perfectly
intelligent approach for
somebody to try with discipline. It's just not something that I've
done.
Finding 'em big obviously is very hard because of the
competition. So far, Berkshire's
managed to do it. But can we continue to do it? What's the next
Coca-Cola investment
for us? Well, the answer to that is I don't know. I think it gets
harder for us all the
Y Combinator: Elementary Worldly Wisdom
http://ycombinator.com/munger.html
18 of 22 9/18/2012 5:17 PM
time....
And ideally and we've done a lot of this—you get into a great
business which also has
a great manager because management matters. For example, it's
made a great
difference to General Electric that Jack Welch came in instead
of the guy who took
over Westinghouse—a very great difference. So management
matters, too.
And some of it is predictable. I do not think it takes a genius to
understand that Jack
Welch was a more insightful person and a better manager than
his peers in other
companies. Nor do I think it took tremendous genius to
understand that Disney had
basic momentums in place which are very powerful and that
Eisner and Wells were
very unusual managers.
So you do get an occasional opportunity to get into a wonderful
business that's being
run by a wonderful manager. And, of course, that's hog heaven
day. If you don't load
up when you get those opportunities, it's a big mistake.
Occasionally, you'll find a human being who's so talented that
he can do things that
ordinary skilled mortals can't. I would argue that Simon
Marks—who was second
generation in Marks & Spencer of England—was such a man.
Patterson was such a
man at National Cash Register. And Sam Walton was such a
man.
These people do come along—and in many cases, they're not all
that hard to identify.
If they've got a reasonable hand—with the fanaticism and
intelligence and so on that
these people generally bring to the party—then management can
matter much.
However, averaged out, betting on the quality of a business is
better than betting on
the quality of management. In other words, if you have to
choose one, bet on the
business momentum, not the brilliance of the manager.
But, very rarely, you find a manager who's so good that you're
wise to follow him into
what looks like a mediocre business.
Another very simple effect I very seldom see discussed either
by investment
managers or anybody else is the effect of taxes. If you're going
to buy something
which compounds for 30 years at 15% per annum and you pay
one 35% tax at the
very end, the way that works out is that after taxes, you keep
13.3% per annum.
In contrast, if you bought the same investment, but had to pay
taxes every year of
35% out of the 15% that you earned, then your return would be
15% minus 35% of
15%—or only 9.75% per year compounded. So the difference
there is over 3.5%. And
what 3.5% does to the numbers over long holding periods like
30 years is truly
eye-opening. If you sit back for long, long stretches in great
companies, you can get a
huge edge from nothing but the way that income taxes work.
Even with a 10% per annum investment, paying a 35% tax at the
end gives you 8.3%
after taxes as an annual compounded result after 30 years. In
contrast, if you pay the
35% each year instead of at the end, your annual result goes
down to 6.5%. So you
add nearly 2% of after-tax return per annum if you only achieve
an average return by
historical standards from common stock investments in
companies with tiny dividend
payout ratios.
But in terms of business mistakes that I've seen over a long
lifetime, I would say that
trying to minimize taxes too much is one of the great standard
causes of really dumb
mistakes. I see terrible mistakes from people being overly
motivated by tax
considerations.
Warren and I personally don't drill oil wells. We pay our taxes.
And we've done pretty
well, so far. Anytime somebody offers you a tax shelter from
here on in life, my
advice would be don't buy it.
Y Combinator: Elementary Worldly Wisdom
http://ycombinator.com/munger.html
19 of 22 9/18/2012 5:17 PM
In fact, any time anybody offers you anything with a big
commission and a 200-page
prospectus, don't buy it. Occasionally, you'll be wrong if you
adopt "Munger's Rule".
However, over a lifetime, you'll be a long way ahead—and you
will miss a lot of
unhappy experiences that might otherwise reduce your love for
your fellow man.
There are huge advantages for an individual to get into a
position where you make a
few great investments and just sit back and wait: You're paying
less to brokers.
You're listening to less nonsense. And if it works, the
governmental tax system gives
you an extra 1, 2 or 3 percentage points per annum
compounded.
And you think that most of you are going to get that much
advantage by hiring
investment counselors and paying them 1% to run around,
incurring a lot of taxes on
your behalf'? Lots of luck.
Are there any dangers in this philosophy? Yes. Everything in
life has dangers. Since
it's so obvious that investing in great companies works, it gets
horribly overdone from
time to time. In the "Nifty-Fifty" days, everybody could tell
which companies were the
great ones. So they got up to 50, 60 and 70 times earnings. And
just as IBM fell off
the wave, other companies did, too. Thus, a large investment
disaster resulted from
too high prices. And you've got to be aware of that danger....
So there are risks. Nothing is automatic and easy. But if you can
find some fairly-
priced great company and buy it and sit, that tends to work out
very, very well indeed
—especially for an individual,
Within the growth stock model, there's a sub-position: There are
actually businesses,
that you will find a few times in a lifetime, where any manager
could raise the return
enormously just by raising prices—and yet they haven't done it.
So they have huge
untapped pricing power that they're not using. That is the
ultimate no-brainer.
That existed in Disney. It's such a unique experience to take
your grandchild to
Disneyland. You're not doing it that often. And there are lots of
people in the country.
And Disney found that it could raise those prices a lot and the
attendance stayed right
up.
So a lot of the great record of Eisner and Wells was utter
brilliance but the rest came
from just raising prices at Disneyland and Disneyworld and
through video cassette
sales of classic animated movies.
At Berkshire Hathaway, Warren and I raised the prices of See's
Candy a little faster
than others might have. And, of course, we invested in Coca-
Cola—which had some
untapped pricing power. And it also had brilliant management.
So a Goizueta and
Keough could do much more than raise prices. It was perfect.
You will get a few opportunities to profit from finding
underpricing. There are actually
people out there who don't price everything as high as the
market will easily stand.
And once you figure that out, it's like finding in the street—if
you have the courage of
your convictions.
If you look at Berkshire's investments where a lot of the
money's been made and you
look for the models, you can see that we twice bought into
twonewspaper towns
which have since become onenewspaper towns. So we made a
bet to some extent....
In one of those—The Washington Post—we bought it at about
20% of the value to a
private owner. So we bought it on a Ben Grahamstyle basis—at
onefifth of obvious
value—and, in addition, we faced a situation where you had
both the top hand in a
game that was clearly going to end up with one winner and a
management with a lot
of integrity and intelligence. That one was a real dream. They're
very high class
people—the Katharine Graham family. That's why it was a
dream—an absolute, damn
dream.
Y Combinator: Elementary Worldly Wisdom
http://ycombinator.com/munger.html
20 of 22 9/18/2012 5:17 PM
Of course, that came about back in '73-74. And that was almost
like 1932. That was
probably a once-in-40-yearstype denouement in the markets.
That investment's up
about 50 times over our cost.
If I were you, I wouldn't count on getting any investment in
your lifetime quite as
good as The Washington Post was in '73 and '74.
But it doesn't have to be that good to take care of you.
Let me mention another model. Of course, Gillette and Coke
make fairly lowpriced
items and have a tremendous marketing advantage all over the
world. And in
Gillette's case, they keep surfing along new technology which is
fairly simple by the
standards of microchips. But it's hard for competitors to do.
So they've been able to stay constantly near the edge of
improvements in shaving.
There are whole countries where Gillette has more than 90% of
the shaving market.
GEICO is a very interesting model. It's another one of the 100
or so models you ought
to have in your head. I've had many friends in the sick business
fixup game over a
long lifetime. And they practically all use the following
formula—I call it the cancer
surgery formula:
They look at this mess. And they figure out if there's anything
sound left that can live
on its own if they cut away everything else. And if they find
anything sound, they just
cut away everything else. Of course, if that doesn't work, they
liquidate the business.
But it frequently does work.
And GEICO had a perfectly magnificent business submerged in
a mess, but still
working. Misled by success, GEICO had done some foolish
things. They got to thinking
that, because they were making a lot of money, they knew
everything. And they
suffered huge losses.
All they had to do was to cut out all the folly and go back to the
perfectly wonderful
business that was lying there. And when you think about it,
that's a very simple
model. And it's repeated over and over again.
And, in GEICO's case, think about all the money we passively
made.... It was a
wonderful business combined with a bunch of foolishness that
could easily be cut out.
And people were coming in who were temperamentally and
intellectually designed so
they were going to cut it out. That is a model you want to look
for.
And you may find one or two or three in a long lifetime that are
very good. And you
Finally, I'd like to once again talk about investment
management. That is a funny
business because on a net basis, the whole investment
management business
together gives no value added to all buyers combined. That's the
way it has to work.
Of course, that isn't true of plumbing and it isn't true of
medicine. If you're going to
make your careers in the investment management business, you
face a very peculiar
situation. And most investment managers handle it with
psychological denial just like
a chiropractor. That is the standard method of handling the
limitations of the
investment management process. But if you want to live the best
sort of life, I would
urge each of you not to use the psychological denial mode.
I think a select few—a small percentage of the investment
managers—can deliver
value added. But I don't think brilliance alone is enough to do
it. I think that you have
to have a little of this discipline of calling your shots and
loading up—you want to
maximize your chances of becoming one who provides above
average real returns for
clients over the long pull.
Y Combinator: Elementary Worldly Wisdom
http://ycombinator.com/munger.html
21 of 22 9/18/2012 5:17 PM
But I'm just talking about investment managers engaged in
common stock picking. I
am agnostic elsewhere. I think there may well be people who
are so shrewd about
currencies and this, that and the other thing that they can
achieve good longterm
records operating on a pretty big scale in that way. But that
doesn't happen to be my
milieu. I'm talking about stock picking in American stocks.
I think it's hard to provide a lot of value added to the
investment management client,
but it's not impossible.
Y Combinator: Elementary Worldly Wisdom
http://ycombinator.com/munger.html
22 of 22 9/18/2012 5:17 PM
In addition to doing the financial statement, response needs to
be at least 5 sentences in length
Many decisions are based on beliefs
concerning the likelihood of uncertain
events such as the outcome of an elec-
tion, the guilt of a defendant, or the
future value of the dollar. These beliefs
are usually expressed in statements such
as "I think that . .. ," "chances are
. . .," "it is unlikely that . .. ," and
so forth. Occasionally, beliefs concern-
ing uncertain events are expressed in
numerical form as odds or subjective
probabilities. What determines such be-
liefs? How do people assess the prob-
ability of an uncertain event or the
value of an uncertain quantity? This
article shows that people rely on a
limited number of heuristic principles
which reduce the complex tasks of as-
sessing probabilities and predicting val-
ues to simpler judgmental operations.
In general, these heuristics are quite
useful, but sometimes they lead to severe
and systematic errors.
The subjective assessment of proba-
bility resembles the subjective assess-
ment of physical quantities such as
distance or size. These judgments are
all based on data of limited validity,
which are processed according to heu-
ristic rules. For example, the apparent
distance of an object is determined in
part by its clarity. The more sharply the
object is seen, the closer it appears to
be. This rule has some validity, because
in any given scene the more distant
objects are seen less sharply than nearer
objects. However, the reliance on this
rule leads to systematic errors in the
estimation of distance. Specifically, dis-
tances are often overestimated when
visibility is poor because the contours
of objects are blurred. On the other
hand, distances are often underesti-
mated when visibility is good because
the objects are seen sharply. Thus, the
reliance on clarity as an indication of
distance leads to common biases. Such
biases are also found in the intuitive
judgment of probability. This article
describes three heuristics that are em-
ployed to assess probabilities and to
predict values. Biases to which these
heuristics lead are enumerated, and the
applied and theoretical implications of
these observations are discussed.
Representativeness
Many of the probabilistic questions
with which people are concerned belong
to one of the following types: What is
the probability that object A belongs to
class B? What is the probability that
event A originates from process B?
What is the probability that process B
will generate event A? In answering
such questions, people typically rely on
the representativeness heuristic, in
which probabilities are evaluated by the
degree to which A is representative of
B, that is, by the degree to which A
resembles B. For example, when A is
highly representative of B, the proba-
bility that A originates from B is judged
to be high. On the other hand, if A is
not similar to B, the probability that A
originates from B is judged to be low.
For an illustration of judgment by
representativeness, consider an indi-
vidual who has been described by a
former neighbor as follows: "Steve is
very shy and withdrawn, invariably
helpful, but with little interest in peo-
ple, or in the world of reality. A meek
and tidy soul, he has a need for order
and structure, and a passion for detail."
How do people assess the probability
that Steve is engaged in a particular
occupation from a list of possibilities
(for example, farmer, salesman, airline
pilot, librarian, or physician)? How do
people order these occupations from
most to least likely? In the representa-
tiveness heuristic, the probability that
Steve is a librarian, for example, is
assessed by the degree to which he is
representative of, or similar to, the
stereotype of a librarian. Indeed, re-
search with problems of this type has
shown that people order the occupa-
tions by probability and by similarity
in exactly the same way (1). This ap-
proach to the judgment of probability
leads to serious errors, because sim-
ilarity, or representativeness, is not in-
fluenced by several factors that should
affect judgments of probability.
Insensitivity to prior probability of
outcomes. One of the factors that have
no effect on representativeness but
should have a major effect on probabil-
ity is the prior probability, or base-rate
frequency, of the outcomes. In the case
of Steve, for example, the fact that
there are many more farmers than li-
brarians in the population should enter
into any reasonable estimate of the
probability that Steve is a librarian
rather than a farmer. Considerations of
base-rate frequency, however, do not
affect the similarity of Steve to the
stereotypes of librarians and farmers.
If people evaluate probability by rep-
resentativeness, therefore, prior proba-
bilities will be neglected. This hypothesis
was tested in an experiment where prior
probabilities were manipulated (1).
Subjects were shown brief personality
descriptions of several individuals, al-
legedly sampled at random from a
group of 100 professionals-engineers
and lawyers. The subjects were asked
to assess, for each description, the prob-
ability that it belonged to an engineer
rather than to a lawyer. In one experi-
mental condition, subjects were told
that the group from which the descrip-
tions had been drawn consisted of 70
engineers and 30 lawyers. In another
condition, subjects were told that the
group consisted of 30 engineers and 70
lawyers. The odds that any particular
description belongs to an engineer
rather than to a lawyer should be
higher in the first condition, where there
is a majority of engineers, than in the
second condition, where there is a
majority of lawyers. Specifically, it can
be shown by applying Bayes' rule that
the ratio of these odds should be (.7/.3)2,
or 5.44, for each description. In a sharp
violation of Bayes' rule, the subjects
in the two conditions produced essen-
SCIENCE, VOL. 185
Judgment under Uncertainty:
Heuristics and Biases
Biases in judgments reveal some heuristics of
thinking under uncertainty.
Amos Tversky and Daniel Kahneman
The authors are members of the department of
psychology at the Hebrew University, Jerusalem,
Tsrael.
1124
tially the same probability judgments.
Apparently, subjects evaluated the like-
lihood that a particular description be-
longed to an engineer rather than to a
lawyer by the degree to which this
description was representative of the
two stereotypes, with little or no regard
for the prior probabilities of the cate-
gories.
The subjects used prior probabilities
correctly when they had no other infor-
mation. In the absence of a personality
sketch, they judged the probability that
an unknown individual is an engineer
to be .7 and .3, respectively, in the two
base-rate conditions. However, prior
probabilities were effectively ignored
when a description was introduced,
even when this description was totally
uninformative. The responses to the
following description illustrate this phe-
nomenon:
Dick is a 30 year old man. He is mar-
ried with no children. A man of high
ability and high motivation, he promises
to be quite successful in his field. He is
well liked by his colleagues.
This description was intended to convey
no information relevant to the question
of whether Dick is an engineer or a
lawyer. Consequently, the probability
that Dick is an engineer should equal
the proportion of engineers in the
group, as if no description had been
given. The subjects, however, judged
the probability of Dick being an engi-
neer to be .5 regardless of whether the
stated proportion of engineers in the
group was .7 or .3. Evidently, people
respond differently when given no evi-
dence and when given worthless evi-
dence. When no specific evidence is
given, prior probabilities are properly
utilized; when worthless evidence is
given, prior probabilities are ignored
(1).
Insensitivity to sample size. To eval-
uate the probability of obtaining a par-
ticular result in a sample drawn from
a specified population, people typically
apply the representativeness heuristic.
That is, they assess the likelihood of
a sample result, for example, that the
average height in a random sample of
ten men will be 6 feet (180 centi-
meters), by the similarity of this result
to the corresponding parameter (that
is, to the average height in the popula-
tion of men). The similarity of a sam-
ple statistic to a population parameter
does not depend on the size of the
sample. Consequently, if probabilities
are assessed by representativeness, then
the judged probability of a sample sta-
tistic will be essentially independent of
27 SEPTEMBER 1974
sample size. Indeed, when subjects
assessed the distributions of average
height for samples of various sizes,
they produced identical distributions.
For example, the probability of obtain-
ing an average height greater than 6
feet was assigned the same value for
samples of 1000, 100, and 10 men (2).
Moreover, subjects failed to appreciate
the role of sample size even when it
was emphasized in the formulation of
the problem. Consider the following
question:
A certain town is served by two hos-
pitals. In the larger hospital about 45
babies are born each day, and in the
smaller hospital about 15 babies are born
each day. As you know, about 50 percent
of all babies are boys. However, the exact
percentage varies from day to day. Some-
times it may be higher than 50 percent,
sometimes lower.
For a period of 1 year, each hospital
recorded the days on which more than 60
percent of the babies born were boys.
Which hospital do you think recorded
more such days?
- The larger hospital (21)
- The smaller hospital (21)
- A!bout the same (that is, within 5
percent of each other) (53)
The values in parentheses are the num-
ber of undergraduate students who
chose each answer.
Most subjects judged the probability
of obtaining more than 60 percent boys
to be the same in the small and in the
large hospital, presumably because these
events are described by the same sta-
tistic and are therefore equally repre-
sentative of the general population. In
contrast, sampling theory entails that
the expected number of days on which
more than 60 percent of ithe babies are
boys is much greater in the small hos-
pital than in the large one, because a
large sample is less likely to stray from
50 percent. This fundamental notion
of statistics is evidently not part of
people's repertoire of intuitions.
A similar insensitivity to sample size
has been reported in judgments of pos-
terior probability, that is, of the prob-
ability that a sample has been drawn
from one population rather than from
another. Consider the following ex-
ample:
Imagine an urn filled with balls, of
which 2/3 are of one color and ?3 of
another. One individual has drawn 5 balls
,from the urn, and found that 4 were red
and 1 was white Another individual has
drawn 20 balls and found that 12 were
red and 8 were white. Which of the two
individuals should feel more confident that
the urn contains 2/3 red balls and 1/3 white
balls, rather than the opposite? What odds
should each individual give?
In this problem, the correct pos,terior
odds are 8 to 1 for the 4: 1 sample
and 16 to 1 for the 12: 8 sample, as-
suming equal prior probabilities. How-
ever, most people feel that the first
sample provides much stronger evidence
for the hypothesis ithat the urn is pre-
dominantly red, because the proportion
of red balls is larger in the first than in
the second sample. Here again, intuitive
judgments are dominated by the sample
proportion and are essentially unaffected
by the size of the sample, which plays
a crucial role in the determination of
the actual posterior odds (2). In ad-
dition, intuitive estimates of posterior
odds are far less extreme than the cor-
rect values. The underestimation of the
impact of evidence has been observed
repeatedly in problems of this type (3, 4).
It has been labeled "conservatism."
Misconceptions of chance. People ex-
pect that a sequence of events generated
by a random process will represent the
essential characteristics of that process
even when the sequence is short. In
considering tosses of a coin for heads
or tails, for example, people regard the
sequence H-T-H-T-T-H to be more
likely than the sequence H-H-H-T-T-T,
which does not appear random, and
also more likely than the sequence H-H-
H-H-T-H, which does not represent the
fairness of the coin (2). Thus, people
expect that the essential characteristics
of the process will be represented, not
only globally in the entire sequence,
but also locally in each of its parts. A
locally representative sequence, how-
ever, deviates systematically from chance
expectation: it contains too many al-
ternations and too few runs. Another
consequence of the belief in local rep-
resentativeness is the well-known gam-
bler's fallacy. After observing a long
run of red on the roulette wheel. for
example, most people erroneously be-
lieve that black is now due, presumably
because the occurrence of black will
result in a more representative sequence
than the occurrence of an additional
red. Chance is commonly viewed as a
self-correcting process in which a devi-
ation in one direction induces a devia-
tion in the opposite direction to restore
the equilibrium. In fact, deviations are
not "corrected" as a chance process
unfolds, they are merely diluted.
Misconceptions of chance are not
limited to naive subjects. A study of
the statistical intuitions of experienced
research psychologists (5) revealed a
lingering belief in what may be called
the "law of small numbers," according
to which even small samples are highly
1125
representative of the populations from
which they are drawn. The responses
of these investigators reflected the ex-
pectation that a valid hypothesis about
a population will be represented by a
statistically significant result in a sam-
ple-with little regard for its size. As
a consequence, the researchers put too
much faith in the results of small sam-
ples and grossly overestimated the
replicability of such results. In the
actual conduct of research, this bias
leads to ithe selection of samples of
inadequate size and to overinterpretation
of findings.
Insensitivity to predictability. People
are sometimes called upon to make such
numerical predictions as the future value
of a stock, the demand for a commod-
ity, or the outcome of a football game.
Such predictions are often made by
representativeness. For example, sup-
pose one is given a description of a
company and is asked to predict its
future profit. If the description of ithe
company is very favorable, a very
high profit will appear most represen-
tative of that description; if the descrip-
tion is mediocre, a mediocre perform-
ance will appear most representative.
The degree to which the description is
favorable is unaffected by the reliability
of that description or by the degree to
which it permits accurate prediction.
Hence, if people predict solely in terms
of the favorableness of the description,
their predictions will be insensitive to
the reliability of the evidence and to
the expected accuracy of the prediction.
This mode of judgment violates the
normative statistical theory in which
the extremeness and the range of pre-
dictions are controlled by considerations
of predictability. When predictability
is nil, the same prediction should be
made in all cases. For example, if the
descriptions of companies provide no
information relevant to profit, then the
same value (such as average profit)
should be predicted for all companies.
If predictability is perfect, of course,
the values predicted will match the
actual values and the range of predic-
tions will equal the range of outcomes.
In general, the higher the predictability,
the wider the range of predicted values.
Several studies of numerical predic-
tion have demonstrated that intuitive
predictions violate this rule, and that
subjects show little or no regard for
considerations of predictability (1). In
one of these studies, subjects were pre-
sented with several paragraphs, each
describing the performance of a stu-
1126
dent teacher during a particular prac-
tice lesson. Some subjects were asked
to evaluate the quality of the lesson
described in the paragraph in percentile
scores, relative to a specified population.
Other subjects were asked to predict,
also in percentile scores, the standing
of each student teacher 5 years after
the practice lesson. The judgments made
under the two conditions were identical.
That is, the prediction of a remote
criterion (success of a teacher after 5
years) was identical to the evaluation
of the information on which the predic-
tion was based (the quality of the
practice lesson). The students who made
these predictions were undoubtedly
aware of the limited predictability of
teaching competence on the basis of a
single trial lesson 5 years earlier; never-
theless, their predictions were as ex-
treme as their evaluations.
The illusion of validity. As we have
seen, people often predict by selecting
the outcome (for example, an occupa-
tion) that is most representative of the
input (for example, the description of
a person). The confidence they have
in their prediction depends primarily
on the degree of representativeness
(that is, on the quality of the match
between the selected outcome and the
input) with little or no regard for the
factors that limit predictive accuracy.
Thus, people express great confidence
in the prediction that a person is a
librarian when given a description of
his personality which matches the
stereotype of librarians, even if the
description is scanty, unreliable, or out-
dated. The unwarranted confidence
which is produced by a good fit between
the predicted outcome and the input
information may be called the illusion
of validity. This illusion persists even
when the judge is aware of the factors
that limit the accuracy of his predic-
tions. It is a common observation that
psychologists who conduct selection
interviews often experience considerable
confidence in their predictions, even
when they know of the vast literature
that shows selection interviews to be
highly fallible. The continued reliance
on the clinical interview for selection,
despite repeated demonstrations of its
inadequacy, amply attests to the strength
of this effect.
The internal consistency of a pattern
of inputs is a major determinant of
one's confidence in predictions based
on these inputs. For example, people
express more confidence in predicting the
final grade-point average of a student
whose first-year record consists entirely
of B's than in predicting the grade-
point average of a student whose first-
year record includes many A's and C's.
Highly consistent patterns are most
often observed when the input vari-
ables are highly redundant or correlated.
Hence, people tend to have great con-
fidence in predictions based on redun-
dant input variables. However, an
elementary result in the statistics of cor-
relation asserts that, given input vari-
ables of stated validity, a prediction
based on several such inputs can
achieve higher accuracy when they are
independent of each other than when
they are redundant or correlated. Thus,
redundancy among inputs decreases
accuracy even as it increases confidence,
and people are often confident in pre-
dictions that are quite likely to be off
the mark (1).
A Lesson on Elementary, Worldly Wisdom As It Relates To Invest.docx
A Lesson on Elementary, Worldly Wisdom As It Relates To Invest.docx
A Lesson on Elementary, Worldly Wisdom As It Relates To Invest.docx
A Lesson on Elementary, Worldly Wisdom As It Relates To Invest.docx
A Lesson on Elementary, Worldly Wisdom As It Relates To Invest.docx
A Lesson on Elementary, Worldly Wisdom As It Relates To Invest.docx
A Lesson on Elementary, Worldly Wisdom As It Relates To Invest.docx
A Lesson on Elementary, Worldly Wisdom As It Relates To Invest.docx
A Lesson on Elementary, Worldly Wisdom As It Relates To Invest.docx
A Lesson on Elementary, Worldly Wisdom As It Relates To Invest.docx
A Lesson on Elementary, Worldly Wisdom As It Relates To Invest.docx
A Lesson on Elementary, Worldly Wisdom As It Relates To Invest.docx
A Lesson on Elementary, Worldly Wisdom As It Relates To Invest.docx
A Lesson on Elementary, Worldly Wisdom As It Relates To Invest.docx
A Lesson on Elementary, Worldly Wisdom As It Relates To Invest.docx
A Lesson on Elementary, Worldly Wisdom As It Relates To Invest.docx
A Lesson on Elementary, Worldly Wisdom As It Relates To Invest.docx
A Lesson on Elementary, Worldly Wisdom As It Relates To Invest.docx
A Lesson on Elementary, Worldly Wisdom As It Relates To Invest.docx
A Lesson on Elementary, Worldly Wisdom As It Relates To Invest.docx
A Lesson on Elementary, Worldly Wisdom As It Relates To Invest.docx
A Lesson on Elementary, Worldly Wisdom As It Relates To Invest.docx
A Lesson on Elementary, Worldly Wisdom As It Relates To Invest.docx
A Lesson on Elementary, Worldly Wisdom As It Relates To Invest.docx
A Lesson on Elementary, Worldly Wisdom As It Relates To Invest.docx
A Lesson on Elementary, Worldly Wisdom As It Relates To Invest.docx
A Lesson on Elementary, Worldly Wisdom As It Relates To Invest.docx
A Lesson on Elementary, Worldly Wisdom As It Relates To Invest.docx
A Lesson on Elementary, Worldly Wisdom As It Relates To Invest.docx
A Lesson on Elementary, Worldly Wisdom As It Relates To Invest.docx
A Lesson on Elementary, Worldly Wisdom As It Relates To Invest.docx
A Lesson on Elementary, Worldly Wisdom As It Relates To Invest.docx
A Lesson on Elementary, Worldly Wisdom As It Relates To Invest.docx
A Lesson on Elementary, Worldly Wisdom As It Relates To Invest.docx
A Lesson on Elementary, Worldly Wisdom As It Relates To Invest.docx
A Lesson on Elementary, Worldly Wisdom As It Relates To Invest.docx
A Lesson on Elementary, Worldly Wisdom As It Relates To Invest.docx

More Related Content

Similar to A Lesson on Elementary, Worldly Wisdom As It Relates To Invest.docx

Writing A Research Essay.pdf
Writing A Research Essay.pdfWriting A Research Essay.pdf
Writing A Research Essay.pdf
Christina Morgan
 
Seven secrets of_successful_project_management
Seven secrets of_successful_project_managementSeven secrets of_successful_project_management
Seven secrets of_successful_project_management
Business engineer
 

Similar to A Lesson on Elementary, Worldly Wisdom As It Relates To Invest.docx (16)

Pin On Reluctant Homeschool Writers
Pin On Reluctant Homeschool WritersPin On Reluctant Homeschool Writers
Pin On Reluctant Homeschool Writers
 
Writing A Research Essay.pdf
Writing A Research Essay.pdfWriting A Research Essay.pdf
Writing A Research Essay.pdf
 
Essay Writing Service College Admissions Your -
Essay Writing Service College Admissions Your -Essay Writing Service College Admissions Your -
Essay Writing Service College Admissions Your -
 
How We Can Protect Our Environment Essay
How We Can Protect Our Environment EssayHow We Can Protect Our Environment Essay
How We Can Protect Our Environment Essay
 
The Only Skill that Matters
The Only Skill that MattersThe Only Skill that Matters
The Only Skill that Matters
 
Teaching that Sticks
Teaching that SticksTeaching that Sticks
Teaching that Sticks
 
Philosophy Essay Examples. Online assignment writing service.
Philosophy Essay Examples. Online assignment writing service.Philosophy Essay Examples. Online assignment writing service.
Philosophy Essay Examples. Online assignment writing service.
 
How to become great at anything
How to become great at anythingHow to become great at anything
How to become great at anything
 
Writing Paper For 1St Grade - Printa
Writing Paper For 1St Grade - PrintaWriting Paper For 1St Grade - Printa
Writing Paper For 1St Grade - Printa
 
The Help Movie Analysis. The Help Movie Analysis
The Help Movie Analysis. The Help Movie AnalysisThe Help Movie Analysis. The Help Movie Analysis
The Help Movie Analysis. The Help Movie Analysis
 
Writing Paper - Notebook Paper Latest Price, Manufacturers
Writing Paper - Notebook Paper Latest Price, ManufacturersWriting Paper - Notebook Paper Latest Price, Manufacturers
Writing Paper - Notebook Paper Latest Price, Manufacturers
 
Write An Essay In An Hour. Online assignment writing service.
Write An Essay In An Hour. Online assignment writing service.Write An Essay In An Hour. Online assignment writing service.
Write An Essay In An Hour. Online assignment writing service.
 
Essay Music Piracy. Online assignment writing service.
Essay Music Piracy. Online assignment writing service.Essay Music Piracy. Online assignment writing service.
Essay Music Piracy. Online assignment writing service.
 
Creativetime
CreativetimeCreativetime
Creativetime
 
Seven secrets of_successful_project_management
Seven secrets of_successful_project_managementSeven secrets of_successful_project_management
Seven secrets of_successful_project_management
 
Shift Reports
Shift ReportsShift Reports
Shift Reports
 

More from ransayo

Zoe is a second grader with autism spectrum disorders. Zoe’s father .docx
Zoe is a second grader with autism spectrum disorders. Zoe’s father .docxZoe is a second grader with autism spectrum disorders. Zoe’s father .docx
Zoe is a second grader with autism spectrum disorders. Zoe’s father .docx
ransayo
 
Zlatan Ibrahimović – Sports PsychologyOutlineIntroduction .docx
Zlatan Ibrahimović – Sports PsychologyOutlineIntroduction .docxZlatan Ibrahimović – Sports PsychologyOutlineIntroduction .docx
Zlatan Ibrahimović – Sports PsychologyOutlineIntroduction .docx
ransayo
 
Zia 2Do You Choose to AcceptYour mission, should you choose.docx
Zia 2Do You Choose to AcceptYour mission, should you choose.docxZia 2Do You Choose to AcceptYour mission, should you choose.docx
Zia 2Do You Choose to AcceptYour mission, should you choose.docx
ransayo
 
Ziyao LiIAS 3753Dr. Manata HashemiWorking Title The Edu.docx
Ziyao LiIAS 3753Dr. Manata HashemiWorking Title The Edu.docxZiyao LiIAS 3753Dr. Manata HashemiWorking Title The Edu.docx
Ziyao LiIAS 3753Dr. Manata HashemiWorking Title The Edu.docx
ransayo
 
Ziyan Huang (Jerry)Assignment 4Brand PositioningProfessor .docx
Ziyan Huang (Jerry)Assignment 4Brand PositioningProfessor .docxZiyan Huang (Jerry)Assignment 4Brand PositioningProfessor .docx
Ziyan Huang (Jerry)Assignment 4Brand PositioningProfessor .docx
ransayo
 
Zhtavius Moye04192019BUSA 4126SWOT AnalysisDr. Setliff.docx
Zhtavius Moye04192019BUSA 4126SWOT AnalysisDr. Setliff.docxZhtavius Moye04192019BUSA 4126SWOT AnalysisDr. Setliff.docx
Zhtavius Moye04192019BUSA 4126SWOT AnalysisDr. Setliff.docx
ransayo
 
Zichun Gao Professor Karen Accounting 1AIBM FInancial Stat.docx
Zichun Gao Professor Karen Accounting 1AIBM FInancial Stat.docxZichun Gao Professor Karen Accounting 1AIBM FInancial Stat.docx
Zichun Gao Professor Karen Accounting 1AIBM FInancial Stat.docx
ransayo
 
Zheng Hes Inscription This inscription was carved on a stele erec.docx
Zheng Hes Inscription This inscription was carved on a stele erec.docxZheng Hes Inscription This inscription was carved on a stele erec.docx
Zheng Hes Inscription This inscription was carved on a stele erec.docx
ransayo
 
Zhou 1Time and Memory in Two Portal Fantasies An Analys.docx
Zhou 1Time and Memory in Two Portal Fantasies An Analys.docxZhou 1Time and Memory in Two Portal Fantasies An Analys.docx
Zhou 1Time and Memory in Two Portal Fantasies An Analys.docx
ransayo
 
Zhang 1Yixiang ZhangTamara KuzmenkovEnglish 101.docx
Zhang 1Yixiang ZhangTamara KuzmenkovEnglish 101.docxZhang 1Yixiang ZhangTamara KuzmenkovEnglish 101.docx
Zhang 1Yixiang ZhangTamara KuzmenkovEnglish 101.docx
ransayo
 
Zhang 1Nick ZhangMr. BetheaLyric Peotry13.docx
Zhang 1Nick ZhangMr. BetheaLyric Peotry13.docxZhang 1Nick ZhangMr. BetheaLyric Peotry13.docx
Zhang 1Nick ZhangMr. BetheaLyric Peotry13.docx
ransayo
 
Zero plagiarism4 referencesNature offers many examples of sp.docx
Zero plagiarism4 referencesNature offers many examples of sp.docxZero plagiarism4 referencesNature offers many examples of sp.docx
Zero plagiarism4 referencesNature offers many examples of sp.docx
ransayo
 
ZACHARY SHEMTOB AND DAVID LATZachary Shemtob, formerly editor in.docx
ZACHARY SHEMTOB AND DAVID LATZachary Shemtob, formerly editor in.docxZACHARY SHEMTOB AND DAVID LATZachary Shemtob, formerly editor in.docx
ZACHARY SHEMTOB AND DAVID LATZachary Shemtob, formerly editor in.docx
ransayo
 
zctnoFrl+.1Affid ow9iar!(al+{FJr.docx
zctnoFrl+.1Affid ow9iar!(al+{FJr.docxzctnoFrl+.1Affid ow9iar!(al+{FJr.docx
zctnoFrl+.1Affid ow9iar!(al+{FJr.docx
ransayo
 
Zeng Jiawen ZengChenxia Zhu English 3001-015292017Refl.docx
Zeng Jiawen ZengChenxia Zhu English 3001-015292017Refl.docxZeng Jiawen ZengChenxia Zhu English 3001-015292017Refl.docx
Zeng Jiawen ZengChenxia Zhu English 3001-015292017Refl.docx
ransayo
 
zClass 44.8.19§ Announcements§ Go over quiz #1.docx
zClass 44.8.19§ Announcements§ Go over quiz #1.docxzClass 44.8.19§ Announcements§ Go over quiz #1.docx
zClass 44.8.19§ Announcements§ Go over quiz #1.docx
ransayo
 
zClass 185.13.19§ Announcements§ Review of last .docx
zClass 185.13.19§ Announcements§ Review of last .docxzClass 185.13.19§ Announcements§ Review of last .docx
zClass 185.13.19§ Announcements§ Review of last .docx
ransayo
 

More from ransayo (20)

Zoe is a second grader with autism spectrum disorders. Zoe’s father .docx
Zoe is a second grader with autism spectrum disorders. Zoe’s father .docxZoe is a second grader with autism spectrum disorders. Zoe’s father .docx
Zoe is a second grader with autism spectrum disorders. Zoe’s father .docx
 
Zlatan Ibrahimović – Sports PsychologyOutlineIntroduction .docx
Zlatan Ibrahimović – Sports PsychologyOutlineIntroduction .docxZlatan Ibrahimović – Sports PsychologyOutlineIntroduction .docx
Zlatan Ibrahimović – Sports PsychologyOutlineIntroduction .docx
 
Zia 2Do You Choose to AcceptYour mission, should you choose.docx
Zia 2Do You Choose to AcceptYour mission, should you choose.docxZia 2Do You Choose to AcceptYour mission, should you choose.docx
Zia 2Do You Choose to AcceptYour mission, should you choose.docx
 
Ziyao LiIAS 3753Dr. Manata HashemiWorking Title The Edu.docx
Ziyao LiIAS 3753Dr. Manata HashemiWorking Title The Edu.docxZiyao LiIAS 3753Dr. Manata HashemiWorking Title The Edu.docx
Ziyao LiIAS 3753Dr. Manata HashemiWorking Title The Edu.docx
 
Ziyan Huang (Jerry)Assignment 4Brand PositioningProfessor .docx
Ziyan Huang (Jerry)Assignment 4Brand PositioningProfessor .docxZiyan Huang (Jerry)Assignment 4Brand PositioningProfessor .docx
Ziyan Huang (Jerry)Assignment 4Brand PositioningProfessor .docx
 
Zhtavius Moye04192019BUSA 4126SWOT AnalysisDr. Setliff.docx
Zhtavius Moye04192019BUSA 4126SWOT AnalysisDr. Setliff.docxZhtavius Moye04192019BUSA 4126SWOT AnalysisDr. Setliff.docx
Zhtavius Moye04192019BUSA 4126SWOT AnalysisDr. Setliff.docx
 
Zichun Gao Professor Karen Accounting 1AIBM FInancial Stat.docx
Zichun Gao Professor Karen Accounting 1AIBM FInancial Stat.docxZichun Gao Professor Karen Accounting 1AIBM FInancial Stat.docx
Zichun Gao Professor Karen Accounting 1AIBM FInancial Stat.docx
 
Zheng Hes Inscription This inscription was carved on a stele erec.docx
Zheng Hes Inscription This inscription was carved on a stele erec.docxZheng Hes Inscription This inscription was carved on a stele erec.docx
Zheng Hes Inscription This inscription was carved on a stele erec.docx
 
Zhou 1Time and Memory in Two Portal Fantasies An Analys.docx
Zhou 1Time and Memory in Two Portal Fantasies An Analys.docxZhou 1Time and Memory in Two Portal Fantasies An Analys.docx
Zhou 1Time and Memory in Two Portal Fantasies An Analys.docx
 
Zhang 1Yixiang ZhangTamara KuzmenkovEnglish 101.docx
Zhang 1Yixiang ZhangTamara KuzmenkovEnglish 101.docxZhang 1Yixiang ZhangTamara KuzmenkovEnglish 101.docx
Zhang 1Yixiang ZhangTamara KuzmenkovEnglish 101.docx
 
Zhang 1Nick ZhangMr. BetheaLyric Peotry13.docx
Zhang 1Nick ZhangMr. BetheaLyric Peotry13.docxZhang 1Nick ZhangMr. BetheaLyric Peotry13.docx
Zhang 1Nick ZhangMr. BetheaLyric Peotry13.docx
 
Zero trust is a security stance for networking based on not trusting.docx
Zero trust is a security stance for networking based on not trusting.docxZero trust is a security stance for networking based on not trusting.docx
Zero trust is a security stance for networking based on not trusting.docx
 
Zero plagiarism4 referencesNature offers many examples of sp.docx
Zero plagiarism4 referencesNature offers many examples of sp.docxZero plagiarism4 referencesNature offers many examples of sp.docx
Zero plagiarism4 referencesNature offers many examples of sp.docx
 
Zero plagiarism4 referencesLearning ObjectivesStudents w.docx
Zero plagiarism4 referencesLearning ObjectivesStudents w.docxZero plagiarism4 referencesLearning ObjectivesStudents w.docx
Zero plagiarism4 referencesLearning ObjectivesStudents w.docx
 
Zero Plagiarism or receive a grade of a 0.Choose one important p.docx
Zero Plagiarism or receive a grade of a 0.Choose one important p.docxZero Plagiarism or receive a grade of a 0.Choose one important p.docx
Zero Plagiarism or receive a grade of a 0.Choose one important p.docx
 
ZACHARY SHEMTOB AND DAVID LATZachary Shemtob, formerly editor in.docx
ZACHARY SHEMTOB AND DAVID LATZachary Shemtob, formerly editor in.docxZACHARY SHEMTOB AND DAVID LATZachary Shemtob, formerly editor in.docx
ZACHARY SHEMTOB AND DAVID LATZachary Shemtob, formerly editor in.docx
 
zctnoFrl+.1Affid ow9iar!(al+{FJr.docx
zctnoFrl+.1Affid ow9iar!(al+{FJr.docxzctnoFrl+.1Affid ow9iar!(al+{FJr.docx
zctnoFrl+.1Affid ow9iar!(al+{FJr.docx
 
Zeng Jiawen ZengChenxia Zhu English 3001-015292017Refl.docx
Zeng Jiawen ZengChenxia Zhu English 3001-015292017Refl.docxZeng Jiawen ZengChenxia Zhu English 3001-015292017Refl.docx
Zeng Jiawen ZengChenxia Zhu English 3001-015292017Refl.docx
 
zClass 44.8.19§ Announcements§ Go over quiz #1.docx
zClass 44.8.19§ Announcements§ Go over quiz #1.docxzClass 44.8.19§ Announcements§ Go over quiz #1.docx
zClass 44.8.19§ Announcements§ Go over quiz #1.docx
 
zClass 185.13.19§ Announcements§ Review of last .docx
zClass 185.13.19§ Announcements§ Review of last .docxzClass 185.13.19§ Announcements§ Review of last .docx
zClass 185.13.19§ Announcements§ Review of last .docx
 

Recently uploaded

Recently uploaded (20)

Interdisciplinary_Insights_Data_Collection_Methods.pptx
Interdisciplinary_Insights_Data_Collection_Methods.pptxInterdisciplinary_Insights_Data_Collection_Methods.pptx
Interdisciplinary_Insights_Data_Collection_Methods.pptx
 
REMIFENTANIL: An Ultra short acting opioid.pptx
REMIFENTANIL: An Ultra short acting opioid.pptxREMIFENTANIL: An Ultra short acting opioid.pptx
REMIFENTANIL: An Ultra short acting opioid.pptx
 
On_Translating_a_Tamil_Poem_by_A_K_Ramanujan.pptx
On_Translating_a_Tamil_Poem_by_A_K_Ramanujan.pptxOn_Translating_a_Tamil_Poem_by_A_K_Ramanujan.pptx
On_Translating_a_Tamil_Poem_by_A_K_Ramanujan.pptx
 
How to Create and Manage Wizard in Odoo 17
How to Create and Manage Wizard in Odoo 17How to Create and Manage Wizard in Odoo 17
How to Create and Manage Wizard in Odoo 17
 
Exploring_the_Narrative_Style_of_Amitav_Ghoshs_Gun_Island.pptx
Exploring_the_Narrative_Style_of_Amitav_Ghoshs_Gun_Island.pptxExploring_the_Narrative_Style_of_Amitav_Ghoshs_Gun_Island.pptx
Exploring_the_Narrative_Style_of_Amitav_Ghoshs_Gun_Island.pptx
 
Google Gemini An AI Revolution in Education.pptx
Google Gemini An AI Revolution in Education.pptxGoogle Gemini An AI Revolution in Education.pptx
Google Gemini An AI Revolution in Education.pptx
 
Kodo Millet PPT made by Ghanshyam bairwa college of Agriculture kumher bhara...
Kodo Millet  PPT made by Ghanshyam bairwa college of Agriculture kumher bhara...Kodo Millet  PPT made by Ghanshyam bairwa college of Agriculture kumher bhara...
Kodo Millet PPT made by Ghanshyam bairwa college of Agriculture kumher bhara...
 
Single or Multiple melodic lines structure
Single or Multiple melodic lines structureSingle or Multiple melodic lines structure
Single or Multiple melodic lines structure
 
ICT Role in 21st Century Education & its Challenges.pptx
ICT Role in 21st Century Education & its Challenges.pptxICT Role in 21st Century Education & its Challenges.pptx
ICT Role in 21st Century Education & its Challenges.pptx
 
Jamworks pilot and AI at Jisc (20/03/2024)
Jamworks pilot and AI at Jisc (20/03/2024)Jamworks pilot and AI at Jisc (20/03/2024)
Jamworks pilot and AI at Jisc (20/03/2024)
 
Plant propagation: Sexual and Asexual propapagation.pptx
Plant propagation: Sexual and Asexual propapagation.pptxPlant propagation: Sexual and Asexual propapagation.pptx
Plant propagation: Sexual and Asexual propapagation.pptx
 
How to Give a Domain for a Field in Odoo 17
How to Give a Domain for a Field in Odoo 17How to Give a Domain for a Field in Odoo 17
How to Give a Domain for a Field in Odoo 17
 
ICT role in 21st century education and it's challenges.
ICT role in 21st century education and it's challenges.ICT role in 21st century education and it's challenges.
ICT role in 21st century education and it's challenges.
 
Mehran University Newsletter Vol-X, Issue-I, 2024
Mehran University Newsletter Vol-X, Issue-I, 2024Mehran University Newsletter Vol-X, Issue-I, 2024
Mehran University Newsletter Vol-X, Issue-I, 2024
 
Sensory_Experience_and_Emotional_Resonance_in_Gabriel_Okaras_The_Piano_and_Th...
Sensory_Experience_and_Emotional_Resonance_in_Gabriel_Okaras_The_Piano_and_Th...Sensory_Experience_and_Emotional_Resonance_in_Gabriel_Okaras_The_Piano_and_Th...
Sensory_Experience_and_Emotional_Resonance_in_Gabriel_Okaras_The_Piano_and_Th...
 
Sociology 101 Demonstration of Learning Exhibit
Sociology 101 Demonstration of Learning ExhibitSociology 101 Demonstration of Learning Exhibit
Sociology 101 Demonstration of Learning Exhibit
 
Holdier Curriculum Vitae (April 2024).pdf
Holdier Curriculum Vitae (April 2024).pdfHoldier Curriculum Vitae (April 2024).pdf
Holdier Curriculum Vitae (April 2024).pdf
 
Unit 3 Emotional Intelligence and Spiritual Intelligence.pdf
Unit 3 Emotional Intelligence and Spiritual Intelligence.pdfUnit 3 Emotional Intelligence and Spiritual Intelligence.pdf
Unit 3 Emotional Intelligence and Spiritual Intelligence.pdf
 
Basic Civil Engineering first year Notes- Chapter 4 Building.pptx
Basic Civil Engineering first year Notes- Chapter 4 Building.pptxBasic Civil Engineering first year Notes- Chapter 4 Building.pptx
Basic Civil Engineering first year Notes- Chapter 4 Building.pptx
 
TỔNG ÔN TẬP THI VÀO LỚP 10 MÔN TIẾNG ANH NĂM HỌC 2023 - 2024 CÓ ĐÁP ÁN (NGỮ Â...
TỔNG ÔN TẬP THI VÀO LỚP 10 MÔN TIẾNG ANH NĂM HỌC 2023 - 2024 CÓ ĐÁP ÁN (NGỮ Â...TỔNG ÔN TẬP THI VÀO LỚP 10 MÔN TIẾNG ANH NĂM HỌC 2023 - 2024 CÓ ĐÁP ÁN (NGỮ Â...
TỔNG ÔN TẬP THI VÀO LỚP 10 MÔN TIẾNG ANH NĂM HỌC 2023 - 2024 CÓ ĐÁP ÁN (NGỮ Â...
 

A Lesson on Elementary, Worldly Wisdom As It Relates To Invest.docx

  • 1. A Lesson on Elementary, Worldly Wisdom As It Relates To Investment Management & Business Charles Munger, USC Business School, 1994 I'm going to play a minor trick on you today because the subject of my talk is the art of stock picking as a subdivision of the art of worldly wisdom. That enables me to start talking about worldly wisdom—a much broader topic that interests me because I think all too little of it is delivered by modern educational systems, at least in an effective way. And therefore, the talk is sort of along the lines that some behaviorist psychologists call Grandma's rule after the wisdom of Grandma when she said that you have to eat the carrots before you get the dessert. The carrot part of this talk is about the general subject of worldly wisdom which is a pretty good way to start. After all, the theory of modern education is that you need a general education before you specialize. And I think to some extent, before you're going to be a great stock picker, you need some general education. So, emphasizing what I sometimes waggishly call remedial worldly wisdom, I'm going
  • 2. to start by waltzing you through a few basic notions. What is elementary, worldly wisdom? Well, the first rule is that you can't really know anything if you just remember isolated facts and try and bang 'em back. If the facts don't hang together on a latticework of theory, you don't have them in a usable form. You've got to have models in your head. And you've got to array your experience—both vicarious and direct—on this latticework of models. You may have noticed students who just try to remember and pound back what is remembered. Well, they fail in school and in life. You've got to hang experience on a latticework of models in your head. What are the models? Well, the first rule is that you've got to have multiple models —because if you just have one or two that you're using, the nature of human psychology is such that you'll torture reality so that it fits your models, or at least you'll think it does. You become the equivalent of a chiropractor who, of course, is the great boob in medicine. It's like the old saying, "To the man with only a hammer, every problem looks like a nail." And of course, that's the way the chiropractor goes about practicing medicine. But that's a perfectly disastrous way to think and a perfectly disastrous way to operate in the world. So you've got to have multiple models.
  • 3. And the models have to come from multiple disciplines— because all the wisdom of the world is not to be found in one little academic department. That's why poetry professors, by and large, are so unwise in a worldly sense. They don't have enough models in their heads. So you've got to have models across a fair array of disciplines. You may say, "My God, this is already getting way too tough." But, fortunately, it isn't that tough—because 80 or 90 important models will carry about 90% of the freight in making you a worldly-wise person. And, of those, only a mere handful really carry very heavy freight. So let's briefly review what kind of models and techniques constitute this basic knowledge that everybody has to have before they proceed to being really good at a narrow art like stock picking. First there's mathematics. Obviously, you've got to be able to handle numbers and quantities—basic arithmetic. And the great useful model, after compound interest, is the elementary math of permutations and combinations. And that was taught in my Y Combinator: Elementary Worldly Wisdom http://ycombinator.com/munger.html 1 of 22 9/18/2012 5:17 PM
  • 4. bengbengbb Highlight bengbengbb Highlight bengbengbb Highlight bengbengbb Highlight bengbengbb Highlight day in the sophomore year in high school. I suppose by now in great private schools, it's probably down to the eighth grade or so. It's very simple algebra. It was all worked out in the course of about one year between Pascal and Fermat. They worked it out casually in a series of letters. It's not that hard to learn. What is hard is to get so you use it routinely almost everyday of your life. The Fermat/Pascal system is dramatically consonant with the way that the world works. And it's fundamental truth. So you simply have to have the technique. Many educational institutions—although not nearly enough— have realized this. At
  • 5. Harvard Business School, the great quantitative thing that bonds the first-year class together is what they call decision tree theory. All they do is take high school algebra and apply it to real life problems. And the students love it. They're amazed to find that high school algebra works in life.... By and large, as it works out, people can't naturally and automatically do this. If you understand elementary psychology, the reason they can't is really quite simple: The basic neural network of the brain is there through broad genetic and cultural evolution. And it's not Fermat/Pascal. It uses a very crude, shortcut-type of approximation. It's got elements of Fermat/Pascal in it. However, it's not good. So you have to learn in a very usable way this very elementary math and use it routinely in life—just the way if you want to become a golfer, you can't use the natural swing that broad evolution gave you. You have to learn—to have a certain grip and swing in a different way to realize your full potential as a golfer. If you don't get this elementary, but mildly unnatural, mathematics of elementary probability into your repertoire, then you go through a long life like a onelegged man in an asskicking contest. You're giving a huge advantage to everybody else. One of the advantages of a fellow like Buffett, whom I've
  • 6. worked with all these years, is that he automatically thinks in terms of decision trees and the elementary math of permutations and combinations.... Obviously, you have to know accounting. It's the language of practical business life. It was a very useful thing to deliver to civilization. I've heard it came to civilization through Venice which of course was once the great commercial power in the Mediterranean. However, double-entry bookkeeping was a hell of an invention. And it's not that hard to understand. But you have to know enough about it to understand its limitations—because although accounting is the starting place, it's only a crude approximation. And it's not very hard to understand its limitations. For example, everyone can see that you have to more or less just guess at the useful life of a jet airplane or anything like that. Just because you express the depreciation rate in neat numbers doesn't make it anything you really know. In terms of the limitations of accounting, one of my favorite stories involves a very great businessman named Carl Braun who created the CF Braun Engineering Company. It designed and built oil refineries—which is very hard to do. And Braun would get them to come in on time and not blow up and have efficiencies and so
  • 7. forth. This is a major art. And Braun, being the thorough Teutonic type that he was, had a number of quirks. And one of them was that he took a look at standard accounting and the way it was applied to building oil refineries and he said, "This is asinine." So he threw all of his accountants out and he took his engineers and said, "Now, we'll Y Combinator: Elementary Worldly Wisdom http://ycombinator.com/munger.html 2 of 22 9/18/2012 5:17 PM bengbengbb Highlight bengbengbb Highlight bengbengbb Highlight bengbengbb Highlight devise our own system of accounting to handle this process." And in due time, accounting adopted a lot of Carl Braun's notions. So he was a formidably willful and talented man who demonstrated both the importance of accounting and the
  • 8. importance of knowing its limitations. He had another rule, from psychology, which, if you're interested in wisdom, ought to be part of your repertoire—like the elementary mathematics of permutations and combinations. His rule for all the Braun Company's communications was called the five W's—you had to tell who was going to do what, where, when and why. And if you wrote a letter or directive in the Braun Company telling somebody to do something, and you didn't tell him why, you could get fired. In fact, you would get fired if you did it twice. You might ask why that is so important? Well, again that's a rule of psychology. Just as you think better if you array knowledge on a bunch of models that are basically answers to the question, why, why, why, if you always tell people why, they'll understand it better, they'll consider it more important, and they'll be more likely to comply. Even if they don't understand your reason, they'll be more likely to comply. So there's an iron rule that just as you want to start getting worldly wisdom by asking why, why, why, in communicating with other people about everything, you want to include why, why, why. Even if it's obvious, it's wise to stick in the why. Which models are the most reliable? Well, obviously, the
  • 9. models that come from hard science and engineering are the most reliable models on this Earth. And engineering quality control—at least the guts of it that matters to you and me and people who are not professional engineers—is very much based on the elementary mathematics of Fermat and Pascal: It costs so much and you get so much less likelihood of it breaking if you spend this much. It's all elementary high school mathematics. And an elaboration of that is what Deming brought to Japan for all of that quality control stuff. I don't think it's necessary for most people to be terribly facile in statistics. For example, I'm not sure that I can even pronounce the Poisson distribution. But I know what a Gaussian or normal distribution looks like and I know that events and huge aspects of reality end up distributed that way. So I can do a rough calculation. But if you ask me to work out something involving a Gaussian distribution to ten decimal points, I can't sit down and do the math. I'm like a poker player who's learned to play pretty well without mastering Pascal. And by the way, that works well enough. But you have to understand that bellshaped curve at least roughly as well as I do. And, of course, the engineering idea of a backup system is a very powerful idea. The
  • 10. engineering idea of breakpoints—that's a very powerful model, too. The notion of a critical mass—that comes out of physics—is a very powerful model. All of these things have great utility in looking at ordinary reality. And all of this cost-benefit analysis—hell, that's all elementary high school algebra, too. It's just been dolled up a little bit with fancy lingo. I suppose the next most reliable models are from biology/ physiology because, after all, all of us are programmed by our genetic makeup to be much the same. And then when you get into psychology, of course, it gets very much more complicated. But it's an ungodly important subject if you're going to have any worldly wisdom. Y Combinator: Elementary Worldly Wisdom http://ycombinator.com/munger.html 3 of 22 9/18/2012 5:17 PM bengbengbb Highlight bengbengbb Highlight bengbengbb Highlight
  • 11. And you can demonstrate that point quite simply: There's not a person in this room viewing the work of a very ordinary professional magician who doesn't see a lot of things happening that aren't happening and not see a lot of things happening that are happening. And the reason why is that the perceptual apparatus of man has shortcuts in it. The brain cannot have unlimited circuitry. So someone who knows how to take advantage of those shortcuts and cause the brain to miscalculate in certain ways can cause you to see things that aren't there. Now you get into the cognitive function as distinguished from the perceptual function. And there, you are equally—more than equally in fact—likely to be misled. Again, your brain has a shortage of circuitry and so forth—and it's taking all kinds of little automatic shortcuts. So when circumstances combine in certain ways—or more commonly, your fellow man starts acting like the magician and manipulates you on purpose by causing your cognitive dysfunction—you're a patsy. And so just as a man working with a tool has to know its limitations, a man working with his cognitive apparatus has to know its limitations. And this knowledge, by the
  • 12. way, can be used to control and motivate other people.... So the most useful and practical part of psychology—which I personally think can be taught to any intelligent person in a week—is ungodly important. And nobody taught it to me by the way. I had to learn it later in life, one piece at a time. And it was fairly laborious. It's so elementary though that, when it was all over, I felt like a fool. And yeah, I'd been educated at Cal Tech and the Harvard Law School and so forth. So very eminent places miseducated people like you and me. The elementary part of psychology—the psychology of misjudgment, as I call it—is a terribly important thing to learn. There are about 20 little principles. And they interact, so it gets slightly complicated. But the guts of it is unbelievably important. Terribly smart people make totally bonkers mistakes by failing to pay heed to it. In fact, I've done it several times during the last two or three years in a very important way. You never get totally over making silly mistakes. There's another saying that comes from Pascal which I've always considered one of the really accurate observations in the history of thought. Pascal said in essence, "The mind of man at one and the same time is both the glory and the shame of the universe."
  • 13. And that's exactly right. It has this enormous power. However, it also has these standard misfunctions that often cause it to reach wrong conclusions. It also makes man extraordinarily subject to manipulation by others. For example, roughly half of the army of Adolf Hitler was composed of believing Catholics. Given enough clever psychological manipulation, what human beings will do is quite interesting. Personally, I've gotten so that I now use a kind of two-track analysis. First, what are the factors that really govern the interests involved, rationally considered? And second, what are the subconscious influences where the brain at a subconscious level is automatically doing these things—which by and large are useful, but which often misfunction. One approach is rationality—the way you'd work out a bridge problem: by evaluating the real interests, the real probabilities and so forth. And the other is to evaluate the psychological factors that cause subconscious conclusions— many of which are wrong. Y Combinator: Elementary Worldly Wisdom http://ycombinator.com/munger.html 4 of 22 9/18/2012 5:17 PM ye Pencil
  • 14. ye Typewritten Text Stop Here ye Typewritten Text bengbengbb Highlight bengbengbb Highlight bengbengbb Highlight bengbengbb Highlight bengbengbb Highlight bengbengbb Highlight Now we come to another somewhat less reliable form of human wisdom —microeconomics. And here, I find it quite useful to think of a free market economy—or partly free market economy—as sort of the equivalent of an ecosystem.... This is a very unfashionable way of thinking because early in
  • 15. the days after Darwin came along, people like the robber barons assumed that the doctrine of the survival of the fittest authenticated them as deserving power—you know, "I'm the richest. Therefore, I'm the best. God's in his heaven, etc." And that reaction of the robber barons was so irritating to people that it made it unfashionable to think of an economy as an ecosystem. But the truth is that it is a lot like an ecosystem. And you get many of the same results. Just as in an ecosystem, people who narrowly specialize can get terribly good at occupying some little niche. Just as animals flourish in niches, similarly, people who specialize in the business world—and get very good because they specialize —frequently find good economics that they wouldn't get any other way. And once we get into microeconomics, we get into the concept of advantages of scale. Now we're getting closer to investment analysis—because in terms of which businesses succeed and which businesses fail, advantages of scale are ungodly important. For example, one great advantage of scale taught in all of the business schools of the world is cost reductions along the so-called experience curve. Just doing something complicated in more and more volume enables human beings, who are trying to
  • 16. improve and are motivated by the incentives of capitalism, to do it more and more efficiently. The very nature of things is that if you get a whole lot of volume through your joint, you get better at processing that volume. That's an enormous advantage. And it has a lot to do with which businesses succeed and fail.... Let's go through a list—albeit an incomplete one—of possible advantages of scale. Some come from simple geometry. If you're building a great spherical tank, obviously as you build it bigger, the amount of steel you use in the surface goes up with the square and the cubic volume goes up with the cube. So as you increase the dimensions, you can hold a lot more volume per unit area of steel. And there are all kinds of things like that where the simple geometry—the simple reality—gives you an advantage of scale. For example, you can get advantages of scale from TV advertising. When TV advertising first arrived—when talking color pictures first came into our living rooms—it was an unbelievably powerful thing. And in the early days, we had three networks that had whatever it was—say 90% of the audience. Well, if you were Procter & Gamble, you could afford to use this new method of advertising. You could afford the very expensive cost of
  • 17. network television because you were selling so many cans and bottles. Some little guy couldn't. And there was no way of buying it in part. Therefore, he couldn't use it. In effect, if you didn't have a big volume, you couldn't use network TV advertising which was the most effective technique. So when TV came in, the branded companies that were already big got a huge tail wind. Indeed, they prospered and prospered and prospered until some of them got fat and foolish, which happens with prosperity—at least to some people.... And your advantage of scale can be an informational advantage. If I go to some Y Combinator: Elementary Worldly Wisdom http://ycombinator.com/munger.html 5 of 22 9/18/2012 5:17 PM remote place, I may see Wrigley chewing gum alongside Glotz's chewing gum. Well, I know that Wrigley is a satisfactory product, whereas I don't know anything about Glotz's. So if one is 40 cents and the other is 30 cents, am I going to take something I don't know and put it in my mouth—which is a pretty personal place, after all—for a lousy dime?
  • 18. So, in effect, Wrigley , simply by being so well known, has advantages of scale—what you might call an informational advantage. Another advantage of scale comes from psychology. The psychologists use the term social proof. We are all influenced—subconsciously and to some extent consciously—by what we see others do and approve. Therefore, if everybody's buying something, we think it's better. We don't like to be the one guy who's out of step. Again, some of this is at a subconscious level and some of it isn't. Sometimes, we consciously and rationally think, "Gee, I don't know much about this. They know more than I do. Therefore, why shouldn't I follow them?" The social proof phenomenon which comes right out of psychology gives huge advantages to scale—for example, with very wide distribution, which of course is hard to get. One advantage of Coca-Cola is that it's available almost everywhere in the world. Well, suppose you have a little soft drink. Exactly how do you make it available all over the Earth? The worldwide distribution setup—which is slowly won by a big enterprise—gets to be a huge advantage.... And if you think about it, once you get enough advantages of that type, it can become very hard for anybody to dislodge you.
  • 19. There's another kind of advantage to scale. In some businesses, the very nature of things is to sort of cascade toward the overwhelming dominance of one firm. The most obvious one is daily newspapers. There's practically no city left in the U.S., aside from a few very big ones, where there's more than one daily newspaper. And again, that's a scale thing. Once I get most of the circulation, I get most of the advertising. And once I get most of the advertising and circulation, why would anyone want the thinner paper with less information in it? So it tends to cascade to a winnertakeall situation. And that's a separate form of the advantages of scale phenomenon. Similarly, all these huge advantages of scale allow greater specialization within the firm. Therefore, each person can be better at what he does. And these advantages of scale are so great, for example, that when Jack Welch came into General Electric, he just said, "To hell with it. We're either going to be # 1 or #2 in every field we're in or we're going to be out. I don't care how many people I have to fire and what I have to sell. We're going to be #1 or #2 or out." That was a very toughminded thing to do, but I think it was a very correct decision if
  • 20. you're thinking about maximizing shareholder wealth. And I don't think it's a bad thing to do for a civilization either, because I think that General Electric is stronger for having Jack Welch there. And there are also disadvantages of scale. For example, we—by which I mean Berkshire Hathaway—are the largest shareholder in Capital Cities/ABC. And we had trade publications there that got murdered where our competitors beat us. And the way they beat us was by going to a narrower specialization. We'd have a travel magazine for business travel. So somebody would create one which was addressed solely at corporate travel departments. Like an ecosystem, Y Combinator: Elementary Worldly Wisdom http://ycombinator.com/munger.html 6 of 22 9/18/2012 5:17 PM you're getting a narrower and narrower specialization. Well, they got much more efficient. They could tell more to the guys who ran corporate travel departments. Plus, they didn't have to waste the ink and paper mailing out stuff that corporate travel departments weren't interested in reading. It was a more efficient system. And they beat our brains out as we relied on our broader
  • 21. magazine. That's what happened to The Saturday Evening Post and all those things. They're gone. What we have now is Motocross—which is read by a bunch of nuts who like to participate in tournaments where they turn somersaults on their motorcycles. But they care about it. For them, it's the principal purpose of life. A magazine called Motocross is a total necessity to those people. And its profit margins would make you salivate. Just think of how narrowcast that kind of publishing is. So occasionally, scaling down and intensifying gives you the big advantage. Bigger is not always better. The great defect of scale, of course, which makes the game interesting—so that the big people don't always win—is that as you get big, you get the bureaucracy. And with the bureaucracy comes the territoriality—which is again grounded in human nature. And the incentives are perverse. For example, if you worked for AT&T in my day, it was a great bureaucracy. Who in the hell was really thinking about the shareholder or anything else? And in a bureaucracy, you think the work is done when it goes out of your in-basket into somebody else's in-basket. But, of course, it isn't. It's not done until AT&T delivers what it's supposed to deliver. So you get big, fat, dumb,
  • 22. unmotivated bureaucracies. They also tend to become somewhat corrupt. In other words, if I've got a department and you've got a department and we kind of share power running this thing, there's sort of an unwritten rule: "If you won't bother me, I won't bother you and we're both happy." So you get layers of management and associated costs that nobody needs. Then, while people are justifying all these layers, it takes forever to get anything done. They're too slow to make decisions and nimbler people run circles around them. The constant curse of scale is that it leads to big, dumb bureaucracy—which, of course, reaches its highest and worst form in government where the incentives are really awful. That doesn't mean we don't need governments— because we do. But it's a terrible problem to get big bureaucracies to behave. So people go to stratagems. They create little decentralized units and fancy motivation and training programs. For example, for a big company, General Electric has fought bureaucracy with amazing skill. But that's because they have a combination of a genius and a fanatic running it. And they put him in young enough so he gets a long run. Of course, that's Jack Welch. But bureaucracy is terrible.... And as things get very powerful and very big, you can get some really dysfunctional behavior. Look at Westinghouse.
  • 23. They blew billions of dollars on a bunch of dumb loans to real estate developers. They put some guy who'd come up by some career path—I don't know exactly what it was, but it could have been refrigerators or something—and all of a sudden, he's loaning money to real estate developers building hotels. It's a very unequal contest. And in due time, they lost all those billions of dollars. CBS provides an interesting example of another rule of psychology—namely, Pavlovian association. If people tell you what you really don't want to hear what's unpleasant—there's an almost automatic reaction of antipathy. You have to train yourself out of it. It isn't foredestined that you have to be this way. But you will tend to be this way if you don't think about it. Y Combinator: Elementary Worldly Wisdom http://ycombinator.com/munger.html 7 of 22 9/18/2012 5:17 PM Television was dominated by one network—CBS in its early days. And Paley was a god. But he didn't like to hear what he didn't like to hear. And people soon learned that. So they told Paley only what he liked to hear. Therefore, he was soon living in a little cocoon of unreality and everything else was corrupt— although it was a great
  • 24. business. So the idiocy that crept into the system was carried along by this huge tide. It was a Mad Hatter's tea party the last ten years under Bill Paley. And that is not the only example by any means. You can get severe misfunction in the high ranks of business. And of course, if you're investing, it can make a lot of difference. If you take all the acquisitions that CBS made under Paley, after the acquisition of the network itself, with all his advisors—his investment bankers, management consultants and so forth who were getting paid very handsomely—it was absolutely terrible. For example, he gave something like 20% of CBS to the Dumont Company for a television set manufacturer which was destined to go broke. I think it lasted all of two or three years or something like that. So very soon after he'd issued all of that stock, Dumont was history. You get a lot of dysfunction in a big fat, powerful place where no one will bring unwelcome reality to the boss. So life is an everlasting battle between those two forces—to get these advantages of scale on one side and a tendency to get a lot like the U.S. Agriculture Department on the other side—where they just sit around and so forth. I don't know exactly what they do. However, I do know that they do very little useful work.
  • 25. On the subject of advantages of economies of scale, I find chain stores quite interesting. Just think about it. The concept of a chain store was a fascinating invention. You get this huge purchasing power—which means that you have lower merchandise costs. You get a whole bunch of little laboratories out there in which you can conduct experiments. And you get specialization. If one little guy is trying to buy across 27 different merchandise categories influenced by traveling salesmen, he's going to make a lot of poor decisions. But if your buying is done in headquarters for a huge bunch of stores, you can get very bright people that know a lot about refrigerators and so forth to do the buying. The reverse is demonstrated by the little store where one guy is doing all the buying. It's like the old story about the little store with salt all over its walls. And a stranger comes in and says to the storeowner, "You must sell a lot of salt." And he replies, "No, I don't. But you should see the guy who sells me salt." So there are huge purchasing advantages. And then there are the slick systems of forcing everyone to do what works. So a chain store can be a fantastic enterprise. It's quite interesting to think about Wal-Mart starting from a single store in Bentonville, Arkansas against Sears, Roebuck with its name, reputation and all of its
  • 26. billions. How does a guy in Bentonville, Arkansas with no money blow right by Sears, Roebuck? And he does it in his own lifetime—in fact, during his own late lifetime because he was already pretty old by the time he started out with one little store.... He played the chain store game harder and better than anyone else. Walton invented practically nothing. But he copied everything anybody else ever did that was smart—and he did it with more fanaticism and better employee manipulation. So he just blew right by them all. He also had a very interesting competitive strategy in the early days. He was like a prizefighter who wanted a great record so he could be in the finals and make a big TV hit. So what did he do? He went out and fought 42 palookas. Right? And the result Y Combinator: Elementary Worldly Wisdom http://ycombinator.com/munger.html 8 of 22 9/18/2012 5:17 PM was knockout, knockout, knockout—42 times. Walton, being as shrewd as he was, basically broke other small town merchants in the early days. With his more efficient system, he might not have been able to tackle some titan head-on at the time. But with his better system, he
  • 27. could destroy those small town merchants. And he went around doing it time after time after time. Then, as he got bigger, he started destroying the big boys. Well, that was a very, very shrewd strategy. You can say, "Is this a nice way to behave?" Well, capitalism is a pretty brutal place. But I personally think that the world is better for having Wal- Mart. I mean you can idealize small town life. But I've spent a fair amount of time in small towns. And let me tell you you shouldn't get too idealistic about all those businesses he destroyed. Plus, a lot of people who work at Wal-Mart are very high grade, bouncy people who are raising nice children. I have no feeling that an inferior culture destroyed a superior culture. I think that is nothing more than nostalgia and delusion. But, at any rate, it's an interesting model of how the scale of things and fanaticism combine to be very powerful. And it's also an interesting model on the other side—how with all its great advantages, the disadvantages of bureaucracy did such terrible damage to Sears, Roebuck. Sears had layers and layers of people it didn't need. It was very bureaucratic. It was slow to think. And there was an established way of thinking. If you poked your head up with a new thought, the system kind of turned against you. It
  • 28. was everything in the way of a dysfunctional big bureaucracy that you would expect. In all fairness, there was also much that was good about it. But it just wasn't as lean and mean and shrewd and effective as Sam Walton. And, in due time, all its advantages of scale were not enough to prevent Sears from losing heavily to Wal-Mart and other similar retailers. Here's a model that we've had trouble with. Maybe you'll be able to figure it out better. Many markets get down to two or three big competitors—or five or six. And in some of those markets, nobody makes any money to speak of. But in others, everybody does very well. Over the years, we've tried to figure out why the competition in some markets gets sort of rational from the investor's point of view so that the shareholders do well, and in other markets, there's destructive competition that destroys shareholder wealth. If it's a pure commodity like airline seats, you can understand why no one makes any money. As we sit here, just think of what airlines have given to the world—safe travel, greater experience, time with your loved ones, you name it. Yet, the net amount of money that's been made by the shareholders of airlines since Kitty Hawk, is now a negative figure—a substantial negative figure. Competition was so intense that, once
  • 29. it was unleashed by deregulation, it ravaged shareholder wealth in the airline business. Yet, in other fields—like cereals, for example—almost all the big boys make out. If you're some kind of a medium grade cereal maker, you might make 15% on your capital. And if you're really good, you might make 40%. But why are cereals so profitable—despite the fact that it looks to me like they're competing like crazy with promotions, coupons and everything else? I don't fully understand it. Obviously, there's a brand identity factor in cereals that doesn't exist in airlines. That must be the main factor that accounts for it. And maybe the cereal makers by and large have learned to be less crazy about fighting for market share—because if you get even one person who's hell-bent on Y Combinator: Elementary Worldly Wisdom http://ycombinator.com/munger.html 9 of 22 9/18/2012 5:17 PM gaining market share.... For example, if I were Kellogg and I decided that I had to have 60% of the market, I think I could take most of the profit out of cereals. I'd ruin Kellogg in the process. But I think I could do it.
  • 30. In some businesses, the participants behave like a demented Kellogg. In other businesses, they don't. Unfortunately, I do not have a perfect model for predicting how that's going to happen. For example, if you look around at bottler markets, you'll find many markets where bottlers of Pepsi and Coke both make a lot of money and many others where they destroy most of the profitability of the two franchises. That must get down to the peculiarities of individual adjustment to market capitalism. I think you'd have to know the people involved to fully understand what was happening. In microeconomics, of course, you've got the concept of patents, trademarks, exclusive franchises and so forth. Patents are quite interesting. When I was young, I think more money went into patents than came out. Judges tended to throw them out—based on arguments about what was really invented and what relied on prior art. That isn't altogether clear. But they changed that. They didn't change the laws. They just changed the administration—so that it all goes to one patent court. And that court is now very much more pro-patent. So I think people are now starting to make a lot of money out of owning patents. Trademarks, of course, have always made people a lot of
  • 31. money. A trademark system is a wonderful thing for a big operation if it's well known. The exclusive franchise can also be wonderful. If there were only three television channels awarded in a big city and you owned one of them, there were only so many hours a day that you could be on. So you had a natural position in an oligopoly in the pre-cable days. And if you get the franchise for the only food stand in an airport, you have a captive clientele and you have a small monopoly of a sort. The great lesson in microeconomics is to discriminate between when technology is going to help you and when it's going to kill you. And most people do not get this straight in their heads. But a fellow like Buffett does. For example, when we were in the textile business, which is a terrible commodity business, we were making low-end textiles—which are a real commodity product. And one day, the people came to Warren and said, "They've invented a new loom that we think will do twice as much work as our old ones." And Warren said, "Gee, I hope this doesn't work because if it does, I'm going to close the mill." And he meant it. What was he thinking? He was thinking, "It's a lousy business. We're earning substandard returns and keeping it open just to be nice to the
  • 32. elderly workers. But we're not going to put huge amounts of new capital into a lousy business." And he knew that the huge productivity increases that would come from a better machine introduced into the production of a commodity product would all go to the benefit of the buyers of the textiles. Nothing was going to stick to our ribs as owners. That's such an obvious concept—that there are all kinds of wonderful new inventions that give you nothing as owners except the opportunity to spend a lot more money in a business that's still going to be lousy. The money still won't come to you. All of the advantages from great improvements are going to flow through to the customers. Y Combinator: Elementary Worldly Wisdom http://ycombinator.com/munger.html 10 of 22 9/18/2012 5:17 PM Conversely, if you own the only newspaper in Oshkosh and they were to invent more efficient ways of composing the whole newspaper, then when you got rid of the old technology and got new fancy computers and so forth, all of the savings would come right through to the bottom line. In all cases, the people who sell the machinery—and, by and
  • 33. large, even the internal bureaucrats urging you to buy the equipment—show you projections with the amount you'll save at current prices with the new technology. However, they don't do the second step of the analysis which is to determine how much is going stay home and how much is just going to flow through to the customer. I've never seen a single projection incorporating that second step in my life. And I see them all the time. Rather, they always read: "This capital outlay will save you so much money that it will pay for itself in three years." So you keep buying things that will pay for themselves in three years. And after 20 years of doing it, somehow you've earned a return of only about 4% per annum. That's the textile business. And it isn't that the machines weren't better. It's just that the savings didn't go to you. The cost reductions came through all right. But the benefit of the cost reductions didn't go to the guy who bought the equipment. It's such a simple idea. It's so basic. And yet it's so often forgotten. Then there's another model from microeconomics which I find very interesting. When technology moves as fast as it does in a civilization like ours, you get a phenomenon which I call competitive destruction. You know, you have the finest buggy whip factory and all of a sudden in comes this little horseless
  • 34. carriage. And before too many years go by, your buggy whip business is dead. You either get into a different business or you're dead—you're destroyed. It happens again and again and again. And when these new businesses come in, there are huge advantages for the early birds. And when you're an early bird, there's a model that I call "surfing"—when a surfer gets up and catches the wave and just stays there, he can go a long, long time. But if he gets off the wave, he becomes mired in shallows.... But people get long runs when they're right on the edge of the wave—whether it's Microsoft or Intel or all kinds of people, including National Cash Register in the early days. The cash register was one of the great contributions to civilization. It's a wonderful story. Patterson was a small retail merchant who didn't make any money. One day, somebody sold him a crude cash register which he put into his retail operation. And it instantly changed from losing money to earning a profit because it made it so much harder for the employees to steal.... But Patterson, having the kind of mind that he did, didn't think, "Oh, good for my retail business." He thought, "I'm going into the cash register business." And, of course, he created National Cash Register.
  • 35. And he "surfed". He got the best distribution system, the biggest collection of patents and the best of everything. He was a fanatic about everything important as the technology developed. I have in my files an early National Cash Register Company report in which Patterson described his methods and objectives. And a well-educated orangutan could see that buying into partnership with Patterson in those early days, given his notions about the cash register business, was a total 100% cinch. And, of course, that's exactly what an investor should be looking for. In a long life, you can expect to profit heavily from at least a few of those opportunities if you develop the wisdom and will to seize them. At any rate, "surfing" is a very powerful model. Y Combinator: Elementary Worldly Wisdom http://ycombinator.com/munger.html 11 of 22 9/18/2012 5:17 PM However, Berkshire Hathaway , by and large, does not invest in these people that are "surfing" on complicated technology. After all, we're cranky and idiosyncratic—as you may have noticed. And Warren and I don't feel like we have any great advantage in the high-tech sector.
  • 36. In fact, we feel like we're at a big disadvantage in trying to understand the nature of technical developments in software, computer chips or what have you. So we tend to avoid that stuff, based on our personal inadequacies. Again, that is a very, very powerful idea. Every person is going to have a circle of competence. And it's going to be very hard to advance that circle. If I had to make my living as a musician.... I can't even think of a level low enough to describe where I would be sorted out to if music were the measuring standard of the civilization. So you have to figure out what your own aptitudes are. If you play games where other people have the aptitudes and you don't, you're going to lose. And that's as close to certain as any prediction that you can make. You have to figure out where you've got an edge. And you've got to play within your own circle of competence. If you want to be the best tennis player in the world, you may start out trying and soon find out that it's hopeless—that other people blow right by you. However, if you want to become the best plumbing contractor in Bemidji, that is probably doable by two-thirds of you. It takes a will. It takes the intelligence. But after a while, you'd gradually know all about the plumbing business in Bemidji and master the art. That is an attainable objective, given enough discipline. And people who could never win a
  • 37. chess tournament or stand in center court in a respectable tennis tournament can rise quite high in life by slowly developing a circle of competence— which results partly from what they were born with and partly from what they slowly develop through work. So some edges can be acquired. And the game of life to some extent for most of us is trying to be something like a good plumbing contractor in Bemidji. Very few of us are chosen to win the world's chess tournaments. Some of you may find opportunities "surfing" along in the new high-tech fields—the Intels, the Microsofts and so on. The fact that we don't think we're very good at it and have pretty well stayed out of it doesn't mean that it's irrational for you to do it. Well, so much for the basic microeconomics models, a little bit of psychology, a little bit of mathematics, helping create what I call the general substructure of worldly wisdom. Now, if you want to go on from carrots to dessert, I'll turn to stock picking —trying to draw on this general worldly wisdom as we go. I don't want to get into emerging markets, bond arbitrage and so forth. I'm talking about nothing but plain vanilla stock picking. That, believe me, is complicated enough. And I'm talking about common stock picking. The first question is, "What is the nature of the stock market?"
  • 38. And that gets you directly to this efficient market theory that got to be the rage—a total rage—long after I graduated from law school. And it's rather interesting because one of the greatest economists of the world is a substantial shareholder in Berkshire Hathaway and has been for a long time. His textbook always taught that the stock market was perfectly efficient and that nobody could beat it. But his own money went into Berkshire and made him wealthy. So, like Pascal in his famous wager, he hedged his bet. Is the stock market so efficient that people can't beat it? Well, the efficient market theory is obviously roughly right—meaning that markets are quite efficient and it's quite hard for anybody to beat the market by significant margins as a stock picker by Y Combinator: Elementary Worldly Wisdom http://ycombinator.com/munger.html 12 of 22 9/18/2012 5:17 PM just being intelligent and working in a disciplined way. Indeed, the average result has to be the average result. By definition, everybody can't beat the market. As I always say, the iron rule of life is that only 20% of the people can be in the top fifth. That's just the way it is. So the answer is
  • 39. that it's partly efficient and partly inefficient. And, by the way, I have a name for people who went to the extreme efficient market theory—which is "bonkers". It was an intellectually consistent theory that enabled them to do pretty mathematics. So I understand its seductiveness to people with large mathematical gifts. It just had a difficulty in that the fundamental assumption did not tie properly to reality. Again, to the man with a hammer, every problem looks like a nail. If you're good at manipulating higher mathematics in a consistent way, why not make an assumption which enables you to use your tool? The model I like—to sort of simplify the notion of what goes on in a market for common stocks—is the pari-mutuel system at the racetrack. If you stop to think about it, a pari-mutuel system is a market. Everybody goes there and bets and the odds change based on what's bet. That's what happens in the stock market. Any damn fool can see that a horse carrying a light weight with a wonderful win rate and a good post position etc., etc. is way more likely to win than a horse with a terrible record and extra weight and so on and so on. But if you look at the odds, the bad horse pays 100 to 1, whereas the good horse pays 3 to 2. Then it's not clear
  • 40. which is statistically the best bet using the mathematics of Fermat and Pascal. The prices have changed in such a way that it's very hard to beat the system. And then the track is taking 17% off the top. So not only do you have to outwit all the other betters, but you've got to outwit them by such a big margin that on average, you can afford to take 17% of your gross bets off the top and give it to the house before the rest of your money can be put to work. Given those mathematics, is it possible to beat the horses only using one's intelligence? Intelligence should give some edge, because lots of people who don't know anything go out and bet lucky numbers and so forth. Therefore, somebody who really thinks about nothing but horse performance and is shrewd and mathematical could have a very considerable edge, in the absence of the frictional cost caused by the house take. Unfortunately, what a shrewd horseplayer's edge does in most cases is to reduce his average loss over a season of betting from the 17% that he would lose if he got the average result to maybe 10%. However, there are actually a few people who can beat the game after paying the full 17%. I used to play poker when I was young with a guy who made a substantial living doing nothing but bet harness races.... Now, harness racing is a
  • 41. relatively inefficient market. You don't have the depth of intelligence betting on harness races that you do on regular races. What my poker pal would do was to think about harness races as his main profession. And he would bet only occasionally when he saw some mispriced bet available. And by doing that, after paying the full handle to the house—which I presume was around 17%—he made a substantial living. You have to say that's rare. However, the market was not perfectly efficient. And if it weren't for that big 17% handle, lots of people would regularly be beating lots of other people at the horse races. It's efficient, yes. But it's not perfectly efficient. And with enough shrewdness and fanaticism, some people will get better results than others. The stock market is the same way—except that the house handle is so much lower. If Y Combinator: Elementary Worldly Wisdom http://ycombinator.com/munger.html 13 of 22 9/18/2012 5:17 PM ye Pencil you take transaction costs—the spread between the bid and the ask plus the
  • 42. commissions—and if you don't trade too actively, you're talking about fairly low transaction costs. So that with enough fanaticism and enough discipline, some of the shrewd people are going to get way better results than average in the nature of things. It is not a bit easy. And, of course, 50% will end up in the bottom half and 70% will end up in the bottom 70%. But some people will have an advantage. And in a fairly low transaction cost operation, they will get better than average results in stock picking. How do you get to be one of those who is a winner—in a relative sense—instead of a loser? Here again, look at the pari-mutuel system. I had dinner last night by absolute accident with the president of Santa Anita. He says that there are two or three betters who have a credit arrangement with them, now that they have off-track betting, who are actually beating the house. They're sending money out net after the full handle—a lot of it to Las Vegas, by the way—to people who are actually winning slightly, net, after paying the full handle. They're that shrewd about something with as much unpredictability as horse racing. And the one thing that all those winning betters in the whole history of people who've
  • 43. beaten the pari-mutuel system have is quite simple. They bet very seldom. It's not given to human beings to have such talent that they can just know everything about everything all the time. But it is given to human beings who work hard at it—who look and sift the world for a mispriced be—that they can occasionally find one. And the wise ones bet heavily when the world offers them that opportunity. They bet big when they have the odds. And the rest of the time, they don't. It's just that simple. That is a very simple concept. And to me it's obviously right— based on experience not only from the pari-mutuel system, but everywhere else. And yet, in investment management, practically nobody operates that way. We operate that way—I'm talking about Buffett and Munger. And we're not alone in the world. But a huge majority of people have some other crazy construct in their heads. And instead of waiting for a near cinch and loading up, they apparently ascribe to the theory that if they work a little harder or hire more business school students, they'll come to know everything about everything all the time. To me, that's totally insane. The way to win is to work, work, work, work and hope to have a few insights.
  • 44. How many insights do you need? Well, I'd argue: that you don't need many in a lifetime. If you look at Berkshire Hathaway and all of its accumulated billions, the top ten insights account for most of it. And that's with a very brilliant man—Warren's a lot more able than I am and very disciplined—devoting his lifetime to it. I don't mean to say that he's only had ten insights. I'm just saying, that most of the money came from ten insights. So you can get very remarkable investment results if you think more like a winning pari-mutuel player. Just think of it as a heavy odds against game full of craziness with an occasional mispriced something or other. And you're probably not going to be smart enough to find thousands in a lifetime. And when you get a few, you really load up. It's just that simple. When Warren lectures at business schools, he says, "I could improve your ultimate financial welfare by giving you a ticket with only 20 slots in it so that you had 20 Y Combinator: Elementary Worldly Wisdom http://ycombinator.com/munger.html 14 of 22 9/18/2012 5:17 PM punches—representing all the investments that you got to make in a lifetime. And
  • 45. once you'd punched through the card, you couldn't make any more investments at all." He says, "Under those rules, you'd really think carefully about what you did and you'd be forced to load up on what you'd really thought about. So you'd do so much better." Again, this is a concept that seems perfectly obvious to me. And to Warren it seems perfectly obvious. But this is one of the very few business classes in the U.S. where anybody will be saying so. It just isn't the conventional wisdom. To me, it's obvious that the winner has to bet very selectively. It's been obvious to me since very early in life. I don't know why it's not obvious to very many other people. I think the reason why we got into such idiocy in investment management is best illustrated by a story that I tell about the guy who sold fishing tackle. I asked him, "My God, they're purple and green. Do fish really take these lures?" And he said, "Mister, I don't sell to fish." Investment managers are in the position of that fishing tackle salesman. They're like the guy who was selling salt to the guy who already had too much salt. And as long as the guy will buy salt, why they'll sell salt. But that isn't what ordinarily works for the buyer of investment advice.
  • 46. If you invested Berkshire Hathaway-style, it would be hard to get paid as an investment manager as well as they're currently paid—because you'd be holding a block of Wal-Mart and a block of Coca-Cola and a block of something else. You'd just sit there. And the client would be getting rich. And, after a while, the client would think, "Why am I paying this guy half a percent a year on my wonderful passive holdings?" So what makes sense for the investor is different from what makes sense for the manager. And, as usual in human affairs, what determines the behavior are incentives for the decision maker. From all business, my favorite case on incentives is Federal Express. The heart and soul of their system—which creates the integrity of the product—is having all their airplanes come to one place in the middle of the night and shift all the packages from plane to plane. If there are delays, the whole operation can't deliver a product full of integrity to Federal Express customers. And it was always screwed up. They could never get it done on time. They tried everything—moral suasion, threats, you name it. And nothing worked. Finally, somebody got the idea to pay all these people not so much an hour, but so much a shift—and when it's all done, they can all go home.
  • 47. Well, their problems cleared up overnight. So getting the incentives right is a very, very important lesson. It was not obvious to Federal Express what the solution was. But maybe now, it will hereafter more often be obvious to you. All right, we've now recognized that the market is efficient as a pari-mutuel system is efficient with the favorite more likely than the long shot to do well in racing, but not necessarily give any betting advantage to those that bet on the favorite. In the stock market, some railroad that's beset by better competitors and tough unions may be available at one-third of its book value. In contrast, IBM in its heyday might be selling at 6 times book value. So it's just like the pari- mutuel system. Any damn fool could plainly see that IBM had better business prospects than the railroad. But once you put the price into the formula, it wasn't so clear anymore what was Y Combinator: Elementary Worldly Wisdom http://ycombinator.com/munger.html 15 of 22 9/18/2012 5:17 PM ye Pencil
  • 48. ye Typewritten Text Stop Here going to work best for a buyer choosing between the stocks. So it's a lot like a pari-mutuel system. And, therefore, it gets very hard to beat. What style should the investor use as a picker of common stocks in order to try to beat the market—in other words, to get an above average long- term result? A standard technique that appeals to a lot of people is called "sector rotation". You simply figure out when oils are going to outperform retailers, etc., etc., etc. You just kind of flit around being in the hot sector of the market making better choices than other people. And presumably, over a long period of time, you get ahead. However, I know of no really rich sector rotator. Maybe some people can do it. I'm not saying they can't. All I know is that all the people I know who got rich—and I know a lot of them—did not do it that way. The second basic approach is the one that Ben Graham used— much admired by Warren and me. As one factor, Graham had this concept of value to a private owner—what the whole enterprise would sell for if it were available. And that was calculable in many cases.
  • 49. Then, if you could take the stock price and multiply it by the number of shares and get something that was one third or less of sellout value, he would say that you've got a lot of edge going for you. Even with an elderly alcoholic running a stodgy business, this significant excess of real value per share working for you means that all kinds of good things can happen to you. You had a huge margin of safety—as he put it—by having this big excess value going for you. But he was, by and large, operating when the world was in shell shock from the 1930s—which was the worst contraction in the English- speaking world in about 600 years. Wheat in Liverpool, I believe, got down to something like a 600-year low, adjusted for inflation. People were so shell-shocked for a long time thereafter that Ben Graham could run his Geiger counter over this detritus from the collapse of the 1930s and find things selling below their working capital per share and so on. And in those days, working capital actually belonged to the shareholders. If the employees were no longer useful, you just sacked them all, took the working capital and stuck it in the owners' pockets. That was the way capitalism then worked. Nowadays, of course, the accounting is not realistic because the minute the business starts contracting, significant assets are not there. Under social norms and the new
  • 50. legal rules of the civilization, so much is owed to the employees that, the minute the enterprise goes into reverse, some of the assets on the balance sheet aren't there anymore. Now, that might not be true if you run a little auto dealership yourself. You may be able to run it in such a way that there's no health plan and this and that so that if the business gets lousy, you can take your working capital and go home. But IBM can't, or at least didn't. Just look at what disappeared from its balance sheet when it decided that it had to change size both because the world had changed technologically and because its market position had deteriorated. And in terms of blowing it, IBM is some example. Those were brilliant, disciplined people. But there was enough turmoil in technological change that IBM got bounced off the wave after "surfing" successfully for 60 years. And that was some collapse—an object lesson in the difficulties of technology and one of the reasons why Buffett and Munger don't like technology very much. We don't think we're any good at it, and strange things can happen. At any rate, the trouble with what I call the classic Ben Graham concept is that gradually the world wised up and those real obvious bargains disappeared. You could run your Geiger counter over the rubble and it wouldn't click.
  • 51. Y Combinator: Elementary Worldly Wisdom http://ycombinator.com/munger.html 16 of 22 9/18/2012 5:17 PM But such is the nature of people who have a hammer—to whom, as I mentioned, every problem looks like a nail that the Ben Graham followers responded by changing the calibration on their Geiger counters. In effect, they started defining a bargain in a different way. And they kept changing the definition so that they could keep doing what they'd always done. And it still worked pretty well. So the Ben Graham intellectual system was a very good one. Of course, the best part of it all was his concept of "Mr. Market". Instead of thinking the market was efficient, he treated it as a manic-depressive who comes by every day. And some days he says, "I'll sell you some of my interest for way less than you think it's worth." And other days, "Mr. Market" comes by and says, "I'll buy your interest at a price that's way higher than you think it's worth." And you get the option of deciding whether you want to buy more, sell part of what you already have or do nothing at all. To Graham, it was a blessing to be in business with a manic- depressive who gave you this series of options all the time. That was a very significant
  • 52. mental construct. And it's been very useful to Buffett, for instance, over his whole adult lifetime. However, if we'd stayed with classic Graham the way Ben Graham did it, we would never have had the record we have. And that's because Graham wasn't trying to do what we did. For example, Graham didn't want to ever talk to management. And his reason was that, like the best sort of professor aiming his teaching at a mass audience, he was trying to invent a system that anybody could use. And he didn't feel that the man in the street could run around and talk to managements and learn things. He also had a concept that the management would often couch the information very shrewdly to mislead. Therefore, it was very difficult. And that is still true, of course—human nature being what it is. And so having started out as Grahamites which, by the way, worked fine—we gradually got what I would call better insights. And we realized that some company that was selling at 2 or 3 times book value could still be a hell of a bargain because of momentums implicit in its position, sometimes combined with an unusual managerial skill plainly present in some individual or other, or some system or other. And once we'd gotten over the hurdle of recognizing that a thing
  • 53. could be a bargain based on quantitative measures that would have horrified Graham, we started thinking about better businesses. And, by the way, the bulk of the billions in Berkshire Hathaway have come from the better businesses. Much of the first $200 or $300 million came from scrambling around with our Geiger counter. But the great bulk of the money has come from the great businesses. And even some of the early money was made by being temporarily present in great businesses. Buffett Partnership, for example, owned American Express and Disney when they got pounded down. Most investment managers are in a game where the clients expect them to know a lot about a lot of things. We didn't have any clients who could fire us at Berkshire Hathaway. So we didn't have to be governed by any such construct. And we came to this notion of finding a mispriced bet and loading up when we were very confident that we were right. So we're way less diversified. And I think our system is miles better. However, in all fairness, I don't think a lot of money managers could successfully sell their services if they used our system. But if you're investing for 40 years in some pension fund, what difference does it make if the path from start
  • 54. to finish is a little Y Combinator: Elementary Worldly Wisdom http://ycombinator.com/munger.html 17 of 22 9/18/2012 5:17 PM more bumpy or a little different than everybody else's so long as it's all going to work out well in the end? So what if there's a little extra volatility. In investment management today, everybody wants not only to win, but to have a yearly outcome path that never diverges very much from a standard path except on the upside. Well, that is a very artificial, crazy construct. That's the equivalent in investment management to the custom of binding the feet of Chinese women. It's the equivalent of what Nietzsche meant when he criticized the man who had a lame leg and was proud of it. That is really hobbling yourself. Now, investment managers would say, "We have to be that way. That's how we're measured." And they may be right in terms of the way the business is now constructed. But from the viewpoint of a rational consumer, the whole system's "bonkers" and draws a lot of talented people into socially useless activity. And the Berkshire system is not "bonkers". It's so damned
  • 55. elementary that even bright people are going to have limited, really valuable insights in a very competitive world when they're fighting against other very bright, hardworking people. And it makes sense to load up on the very few good insights you have instead of pretending to know everything about everything at all times. You're much more likely to do well if you start out to do something feasible instead of something that isn't feasible. Isn't that perfectly obvious? How many of you have 56 brilliant ideas in which you have equal confidence? Raise your hands, please. How many of you have two or three insights that you have some confidence in? I rest my case. I'd say that Berkshire Hathaway's system is adapting to the nature of the investment problem as it really is. We've really made the money out of high quality businesses. In some cases, we bought the whole business. And in some cases, we just bought a big block of stock. But when you analyze what happened, the big money's been made in the high quality businesses. And most of the other people who've made a lot of money have done so in high quality businesses. Over the long term, it's hard for a stock to earn a much better return than the
  • 56. business which underlies it earns. If the business earns 6% on capital over 40 years and you hold it for that 40 years, you're not going to make much different than a 6% return—even if you originally buy it at a huge discount. Conversely, if a business earns 18% on capital over 20 or 30 years, even if you pay an expensive looking price, you'll end up with a fine result. So the trick is getting into better businesses. And that involves all of these advantages of scale that you could consider momentum effects. How do you get into these great companies? One method is what I'd call the method of finding them small get 'em when they're little. For example, buy Wal-Mart when Sam Walton first goes public and so forth. And a lot of people try to do just that. And it's a very beguiling idea. If I were a young man, I might actually go into it. But it doesn't work for Berkshire Hathaway anymore because we've got too much money. We can't find anything that fits our size parameter that way. Besides, we're set in our ways. But I regard finding them small as a perfectly intelligent approach for somebody to try with discipline. It's just not something that I've done. Finding 'em big obviously is very hard because of the competition. So far, Berkshire's managed to do it. But can we continue to do it? What's the next Coca-Cola investment
  • 57. for us? Well, the answer to that is I don't know. I think it gets harder for us all the Y Combinator: Elementary Worldly Wisdom http://ycombinator.com/munger.html 18 of 22 9/18/2012 5:17 PM time.... And ideally and we've done a lot of this—you get into a great business which also has a great manager because management matters. For example, it's made a great difference to General Electric that Jack Welch came in instead of the guy who took over Westinghouse—a very great difference. So management matters, too. And some of it is predictable. I do not think it takes a genius to understand that Jack Welch was a more insightful person and a better manager than his peers in other companies. Nor do I think it took tremendous genius to understand that Disney had basic momentums in place which are very powerful and that Eisner and Wells were very unusual managers. So you do get an occasional opportunity to get into a wonderful business that's being run by a wonderful manager. And, of course, that's hog heaven day. If you don't load up when you get those opportunities, it's a big mistake.
  • 58. Occasionally, you'll find a human being who's so talented that he can do things that ordinary skilled mortals can't. I would argue that Simon Marks—who was second generation in Marks & Spencer of England—was such a man. Patterson was such a man at National Cash Register. And Sam Walton was such a man. These people do come along—and in many cases, they're not all that hard to identify. If they've got a reasonable hand—with the fanaticism and intelligence and so on that these people generally bring to the party—then management can matter much. However, averaged out, betting on the quality of a business is better than betting on the quality of management. In other words, if you have to choose one, bet on the business momentum, not the brilliance of the manager. But, very rarely, you find a manager who's so good that you're wise to follow him into what looks like a mediocre business. Another very simple effect I very seldom see discussed either by investment managers or anybody else is the effect of taxes. If you're going to buy something which compounds for 30 years at 15% per annum and you pay one 35% tax at the very end, the way that works out is that after taxes, you keep 13.3% per annum.
  • 59. In contrast, if you bought the same investment, but had to pay taxes every year of 35% out of the 15% that you earned, then your return would be 15% minus 35% of 15%—or only 9.75% per year compounded. So the difference there is over 3.5%. And what 3.5% does to the numbers over long holding periods like 30 years is truly eye-opening. If you sit back for long, long stretches in great companies, you can get a huge edge from nothing but the way that income taxes work. Even with a 10% per annum investment, paying a 35% tax at the end gives you 8.3% after taxes as an annual compounded result after 30 years. In contrast, if you pay the 35% each year instead of at the end, your annual result goes down to 6.5%. So you add nearly 2% of after-tax return per annum if you only achieve an average return by historical standards from common stock investments in companies with tiny dividend payout ratios. But in terms of business mistakes that I've seen over a long lifetime, I would say that trying to minimize taxes too much is one of the great standard causes of really dumb mistakes. I see terrible mistakes from people being overly motivated by tax considerations. Warren and I personally don't drill oil wells. We pay our taxes. And we've done pretty well, so far. Anytime somebody offers you a tax shelter from here on in life, my
  • 60. advice would be don't buy it. Y Combinator: Elementary Worldly Wisdom http://ycombinator.com/munger.html 19 of 22 9/18/2012 5:17 PM In fact, any time anybody offers you anything with a big commission and a 200-page prospectus, don't buy it. Occasionally, you'll be wrong if you adopt "Munger's Rule". However, over a lifetime, you'll be a long way ahead—and you will miss a lot of unhappy experiences that might otherwise reduce your love for your fellow man. There are huge advantages for an individual to get into a position where you make a few great investments and just sit back and wait: You're paying less to brokers. You're listening to less nonsense. And if it works, the governmental tax system gives you an extra 1, 2 or 3 percentage points per annum compounded. And you think that most of you are going to get that much advantage by hiring investment counselors and paying them 1% to run around, incurring a lot of taxes on your behalf'? Lots of luck. Are there any dangers in this philosophy? Yes. Everything in life has dangers. Since it's so obvious that investing in great companies works, it gets
  • 61. horribly overdone from time to time. In the "Nifty-Fifty" days, everybody could tell which companies were the great ones. So they got up to 50, 60 and 70 times earnings. And just as IBM fell off the wave, other companies did, too. Thus, a large investment disaster resulted from too high prices. And you've got to be aware of that danger.... So there are risks. Nothing is automatic and easy. But if you can find some fairly- priced great company and buy it and sit, that tends to work out very, very well indeed —especially for an individual, Within the growth stock model, there's a sub-position: There are actually businesses, that you will find a few times in a lifetime, where any manager could raise the return enormously just by raising prices—and yet they haven't done it. So they have huge untapped pricing power that they're not using. That is the ultimate no-brainer. That existed in Disney. It's such a unique experience to take your grandchild to Disneyland. You're not doing it that often. And there are lots of people in the country. And Disney found that it could raise those prices a lot and the attendance stayed right up. So a lot of the great record of Eisner and Wells was utter brilliance but the rest came from just raising prices at Disneyland and Disneyworld and through video cassette
  • 62. sales of classic animated movies. At Berkshire Hathaway, Warren and I raised the prices of See's Candy a little faster than others might have. And, of course, we invested in Coca- Cola—which had some untapped pricing power. And it also had brilliant management. So a Goizueta and Keough could do much more than raise prices. It was perfect. You will get a few opportunities to profit from finding underpricing. There are actually people out there who don't price everything as high as the market will easily stand. And once you figure that out, it's like finding in the street—if you have the courage of your convictions. If you look at Berkshire's investments where a lot of the money's been made and you look for the models, you can see that we twice bought into twonewspaper towns which have since become onenewspaper towns. So we made a bet to some extent.... In one of those—The Washington Post—we bought it at about 20% of the value to a private owner. So we bought it on a Ben Grahamstyle basis—at onefifth of obvious value—and, in addition, we faced a situation where you had both the top hand in a game that was clearly going to end up with one winner and a management with a lot of integrity and intelligence. That one was a real dream. They're very high class people—the Katharine Graham family. That's why it was a
  • 63. dream—an absolute, damn dream. Y Combinator: Elementary Worldly Wisdom http://ycombinator.com/munger.html 20 of 22 9/18/2012 5:17 PM Of course, that came about back in '73-74. And that was almost like 1932. That was probably a once-in-40-yearstype denouement in the markets. That investment's up about 50 times over our cost. If I were you, I wouldn't count on getting any investment in your lifetime quite as good as The Washington Post was in '73 and '74. But it doesn't have to be that good to take care of you. Let me mention another model. Of course, Gillette and Coke make fairly lowpriced items and have a tremendous marketing advantage all over the world. And in Gillette's case, they keep surfing along new technology which is fairly simple by the standards of microchips. But it's hard for competitors to do. So they've been able to stay constantly near the edge of improvements in shaving. There are whole countries where Gillette has more than 90% of the shaving market. GEICO is a very interesting model. It's another one of the 100
  • 64. or so models you ought to have in your head. I've had many friends in the sick business fixup game over a long lifetime. And they practically all use the following formula—I call it the cancer surgery formula: They look at this mess. And they figure out if there's anything sound left that can live on its own if they cut away everything else. And if they find anything sound, they just cut away everything else. Of course, if that doesn't work, they liquidate the business. But it frequently does work. And GEICO had a perfectly magnificent business submerged in a mess, but still working. Misled by success, GEICO had done some foolish things. They got to thinking that, because they were making a lot of money, they knew everything. And they suffered huge losses. All they had to do was to cut out all the folly and go back to the perfectly wonderful business that was lying there. And when you think about it, that's a very simple model. And it's repeated over and over again. And, in GEICO's case, think about all the money we passively made.... It was a wonderful business combined with a bunch of foolishness that could easily be cut out. And people were coming in who were temperamentally and intellectually designed so they were going to cut it out. That is a model you want to look
  • 65. for. And you may find one or two or three in a long lifetime that are very good. And you Finally, I'd like to once again talk about investment management. That is a funny business because on a net basis, the whole investment management business together gives no value added to all buyers combined. That's the way it has to work. Of course, that isn't true of plumbing and it isn't true of medicine. If you're going to make your careers in the investment management business, you face a very peculiar situation. And most investment managers handle it with psychological denial just like a chiropractor. That is the standard method of handling the limitations of the investment management process. But if you want to live the best sort of life, I would urge each of you not to use the psychological denial mode. I think a select few—a small percentage of the investment managers—can deliver value added. But I don't think brilliance alone is enough to do it. I think that you have to have a little of this discipline of calling your shots and loading up—you want to maximize your chances of becoming one who provides above average real returns for clients over the long pull. Y Combinator: Elementary Worldly Wisdom http://ycombinator.com/munger.html
  • 66. 21 of 22 9/18/2012 5:17 PM But I'm just talking about investment managers engaged in common stock picking. I am agnostic elsewhere. I think there may well be people who are so shrewd about currencies and this, that and the other thing that they can achieve good longterm records operating on a pretty big scale in that way. But that doesn't happen to be my milieu. I'm talking about stock picking in American stocks. I think it's hard to provide a lot of value added to the investment management client, but it's not impossible. Y Combinator: Elementary Worldly Wisdom http://ycombinator.com/munger.html 22 of 22 9/18/2012 5:17 PM In addition to doing the financial statement, response needs to be at least 5 sentences in length
  • 67. Many decisions are based on beliefs concerning the likelihood of uncertain events such as the outcome of an elec- tion, the guilt of a defendant, or the future value of the dollar. These beliefs are usually expressed in statements such as "I think that . .. ," "chances are . . .," "it is unlikely that . .. ," and so forth. Occasionally, beliefs concern- ing uncertain events are expressed in numerical form as odds or subjective probabilities. What determines such be- liefs? How do people assess the prob- ability of an uncertain event or the value of an uncertain quantity? This article shows that people rely on a limited number of heuristic principles which reduce the complex tasks of as- sessing probabilities and predicting val- ues to simpler judgmental operations. In general, these heuristics are quite useful, but sometimes they lead to severe and systematic errors. The subjective assessment of proba- bility resembles the subjective assess- ment of physical quantities such as distance or size. These judgments are all based on data of limited validity, which are processed according to heu- ristic rules. For example, the apparent distance of an object is determined in
  • 68. part by its clarity. The more sharply the object is seen, the closer it appears to be. This rule has some validity, because in any given scene the more distant objects are seen less sharply than nearer objects. However, the reliance on this rule leads to systematic errors in the estimation of distance. Specifically, dis- tances are often overestimated when visibility is poor because the contours of objects are blurred. On the other hand, distances are often underesti- mated when visibility is good because the objects are seen sharply. Thus, the reliance on clarity as an indication of distance leads to common biases. Such biases are also found in the intuitive judgment of probability. This article describes three heuristics that are em- ployed to assess probabilities and to predict values. Biases to which these heuristics lead are enumerated, and the applied and theoretical implications of these observations are discussed. Representativeness Many of the probabilistic questions with which people are concerned belong to one of the following types: What is
  • 69. the probability that object A belongs to class B? What is the probability that event A originates from process B? What is the probability that process B will generate event A? In answering such questions, people typically rely on the representativeness heuristic, in which probabilities are evaluated by the degree to which A is representative of B, that is, by the degree to which A resembles B. For example, when A is highly representative of B, the proba- bility that A originates from B is judged to be high. On the other hand, if A is not similar to B, the probability that A originates from B is judged to be low. For an illustration of judgment by representativeness, consider an indi- vidual who has been described by a former neighbor as follows: "Steve is very shy and withdrawn, invariably helpful, but with little interest in peo- ple, or in the world of reality. A meek and tidy soul, he has a need for order and structure, and a passion for detail." How do people assess the probability that Steve is engaged in a particular occupation from a list of possibilities (for example, farmer, salesman, airline pilot, librarian, or physician)? How do people order these occupations from
  • 70. most to least likely? In the representa- tiveness heuristic, the probability that Steve is a librarian, for example, is assessed by the degree to which he is representative of, or similar to, the stereotype of a librarian. Indeed, re- search with problems of this type has shown that people order the occupa- tions by probability and by similarity in exactly the same way (1). This ap- proach to the judgment of probability leads to serious errors, because sim- ilarity, or representativeness, is not in- fluenced by several factors that should affect judgments of probability. Insensitivity to prior probability of outcomes. One of the factors that have no effect on representativeness but should have a major effect on probabil- ity is the prior probability, or base-rate frequency, of the outcomes. In the case of Steve, for example, the fact that there are many more farmers than li- brarians in the population should enter into any reasonable estimate of the probability that Steve is a librarian rather than a farmer. Considerations of base-rate frequency, however, do not affect the similarity of Steve to the stereotypes of librarians and farmers. If people evaluate probability by rep- resentativeness, therefore, prior proba- bilities will be neglected. This hypothesis was tested in an experiment where prior
  • 71. probabilities were manipulated (1). Subjects were shown brief personality descriptions of several individuals, al- legedly sampled at random from a group of 100 professionals-engineers and lawyers. The subjects were asked to assess, for each description, the prob- ability that it belonged to an engineer rather than to a lawyer. In one experi- mental condition, subjects were told that the group from which the descrip- tions had been drawn consisted of 70 engineers and 30 lawyers. In another condition, subjects were told that the group consisted of 30 engineers and 70 lawyers. The odds that any particular description belongs to an engineer rather than to a lawyer should be higher in the first condition, where there is a majority of engineers, than in the second condition, where there is a majority of lawyers. Specifically, it can be shown by applying Bayes' rule that the ratio of these odds should be (.7/.3)2, or 5.44, for each description. In a sharp violation of Bayes' rule, the subjects in the two conditions produced essen- SCIENCE, VOL. 185 Judgment under Uncertainty:
  • 72. Heuristics and Biases Biases in judgments reveal some heuristics of thinking under uncertainty. Amos Tversky and Daniel Kahneman The authors are members of the department of psychology at the Hebrew University, Jerusalem, Tsrael. 1124 tially the same probability judgments. Apparently, subjects evaluated the like- lihood that a particular description be- longed to an engineer rather than to a lawyer by the degree to which this description was representative of the two stereotypes, with little or no regard for the prior probabilities of the cate- gories. The subjects used prior probabilities correctly when they had no other infor- mation. In the absence of a personality sketch, they judged the probability that an unknown individual is an engineer to be .7 and .3, respectively, in the two base-rate conditions. However, prior probabilities were effectively ignored when a description was introduced, even when this description was totally
  • 73. uninformative. The responses to the following description illustrate this phe- nomenon: Dick is a 30 year old man. He is mar- ried with no children. A man of high ability and high motivation, he promises to be quite successful in his field. He is well liked by his colleagues. This description was intended to convey no information relevant to the question of whether Dick is an engineer or a lawyer. Consequently, the probability that Dick is an engineer should equal the proportion of engineers in the group, as if no description had been given. The subjects, however, judged the probability of Dick being an engi- neer to be .5 regardless of whether the stated proportion of engineers in the group was .7 or .3. Evidently, people respond differently when given no evi- dence and when given worthless evi- dence. When no specific evidence is given, prior probabilities are properly utilized; when worthless evidence is given, prior probabilities are ignored (1). Insensitivity to sample size. To eval- uate the probability of obtaining a par- ticular result in a sample drawn from a specified population, people typically apply the representativeness heuristic. That is, they assess the likelihood of a sample result, for example, that the
  • 74. average height in a random sample of ten men will be 6 feet (180 centi- meters), by the similarity of this result to the corresponding parameter (that is, to the average height in the popula- tion of men). The similarity of a sam- ple statistic to a population parameter does not depend on the size of the sample. Consequently, if probabilities are assessed by representativeness, then the judged probability of a sample sta- tistic will be essentially independent of 27 SEPTEMBER 1974 sample size. Indeed, when subjects assessed the distributions of average height for samples of various sizes, they produced identical distributions. For example, the probability of obtain- ing an average height greater than 6 feet was assigned the same value for samples of 1000, 100, and 10 men (2). Moreover, subjects failed to appreciate the role of sample size even when it was emphasized in the formulation of the problem. Consider the following question: A certain town is served by two hos- pitals. In the larger hospital about 45 babies are born each day, and in the smaller hospital about 15 babies are born each day. As you know, about 50 percent of all babies are boys. However, the exact percentage varies from day to day. Some- times it may be higher than 50 percent,
  • 75. sometimes lower. For a period of 1 year, each hospital recorded the days on which more than 60 percent of the babies born were boys. Which hospital do you think recorded more such days? - The larger hospital (21) - The smaller hospital (21) - A!bout the same (that is, within 5 percent of each other) (53) The values in parentheses are the num- ber of undergraduate students who chose each answer. Most subjects judged the probability of obtaining more than 60 percent boys to be the same in the small and in the large hospital, presumably because these events are described by the same sta- tistic and are therefore equally repre- sentative of the general population. In contrast, sampling theory entails that the expected number of days on which more than 60 percent of ithe babies are boys is much greater in the small hos- pital than in the large one, because a large sample is less likely to stray from 50 percent. This fundamental notion of statistics is evidently not part of people's repertoire of intuitions. A similar insensitivity to sample size has been reported in judgments of pos-
  • 76. terior probability, that is, of the prob- ability that a sample has been drawn from one population rather than from another. Consider the following ex- ample: Imagine an urn filled with balls, of which 2/3 are of one color and ?3 of another. One individual has drawn 5 balls ,from the urn, and found that 4 were red and 1 was white Another individual has drawn 20 balls and found that 12 were red and 8 were white. Which of the two individuals should feel more confident that the urn contains 2/3 red balls and 1/3 white balls, rather than the opposite? What odds should each individual give? In this problem, the correct pos,terior odds are 8 to 1 for the 4: 1 sample and 16 to 1 for the 12: 8 sample, as- suming equal prior probabilities. How- ever, most people feel that the first sample provides much stronger evidence for the hypothesis ithat the urn is pre- dominantly red, because the proportion of red balls is larger in the first than in the second sample. Here again, intuitive judgments are dominated by the sample proportion and are essentially unaffected by the size of the sample, which plays a crucial role in the determination of the actual posterior odds (2). In ad- dition, intuitive estimates of posterior odds are far less extreme than the cor- rect values. The underestimation of the
  • 77. impact of evidence has been observed repeatedly in problems of this type (3, 4). It has been labeled "conservatism." Misconceptions of chance. People ex- pect that a sequence of events generated by a random process will represent the essential characteristics of that process even when the sequence is short. In considering tosses of a coin for heads or tails, for example, people regard the sequence H-T-H-T-T-H to be more likely than the sequence H-H-H-T-T-T, which does not appear random, and also more likely than the sequence H-H- H-H-T-H, which does not represent the fairness of the coin (2). Thus, people expect that the essential characteristics of the process will be represented, not only globally in the entire sequence, but also locally in each of its parts. A locally representative sequence, how- ever, deviates systematically from chance expectation: it contains too many al- ternations and too few runs. Another consequence of the belief in local rep- resentativeness is the well-known gam- bler's fallacy. After observing a long run of red on the roulette wheel. for example, most people erroneously be- lieve that black is now due, presumably because the occurrence of black will result in a more representative sequence than the occurrence of an additional red. Chance is commonly viewed as a self-correcting process in which a devi-
  • 78. ation in one direction induces a devia- tion in the opposite direction to restore the equilibrium. In fact, deviations are not "corrected" as a chance process unfolds, they are merely diluted. Misconceptions of chance are not limited to naive subjects. A study of the statistical intuitions of experienced research psychologists (5) revealed a lingering belief in what may be called the "law of small numbers," according to which even small samples are highly 1125 representative of the populations from which they are drawn. The responses of these investigators reflected the ex- pectation that a valid hypothesis about a population will be represented by a statistically significant result in a sam- ple-with little regard for its size. As a consequence, the researchers put too much faith in the results of small sam- ples and grossly overestimated the replicability of such results. In the actual conduct of research, this bias leads to ithe selection of samples of inadequate size and to overinterpretation of findings. Insensitivity to predictability. People are sometimes called upon to make such
  • 79. numerical predictions as the future value of a stock, the demand for a commod- ity, or the outcome of a football game. Such predictions are often made by representativeness. For example, sup- pose one is given a description of a company and is asked to predict its future profit. If the description of ithe company is very favorable, a very high profit will appear most represen- tative of that description; if the descrip- tion is mediocre, a mediocre perform- ance will appear most representative. The degree to which the description is favorable is unaffected by the reliability of that description or by the degree to which it permits accurate prediction. Hence, if people predict solely in terms of the favorableness of the description, their predictions will be insensitive to the reliability of the evidence and to the expected accuracy of the prediction. This mode of judgment violates the normative statistical theory in which the extremeness and the range of pre- dictions are controlled by considerations of predictability. When predictability is nil, the same prediction should be made in all cases. For example, if the descriptions of companies provide no information relevant to profit, then the same value (such as average profit) should be predicted for all companies. If predictability is perfect, of course, the values predicted will match the
  • 80. actual values and the range of predic- tions will equal the range of outcomes. In general, the higher the predictability, the wider the range of predicted values. Several studies of numerical predic- tion have demonstrated that intuitive predictions violate this rule, and that subjects show little or no regard for considerations of predictability (1). In one of these studies, subjects were pre- sented with several paragraphs, each describing the performance of a stu- 1126 dent teacher during a particular prac- tice lesson. Some subjects were asked to evaluate the quality of the lesson described in the paragraph in percentile scores, relative to a specified population. Other subjects were asked to predict, also in percentile scores, the standing of each student teacher 5 years after the practice lesson. The judgments made under the two conditions were identical. That is, the prediction of a remote criterion (success of a teacher after 5 years) was identical to the evaluation of the information on which the predic- tion was based (the quality of the practice lesson). The students who made these predictions were undoubtedly aware of the limited predictability of teaching competence on the basis of a
  • 81. single trial lesson 5 years earlier; never- theless, their predictions were as ex- treme as their evaluations. The illusion of validity. As we have seen, people often predict by selecting the outcome (for example, an occupa- tion) that is most representative of the input (for example, the description of a person). The confidence they have in their prediction depends primarily on the degree of representativeness (that is, on the quality of the match between the selected outcome and the input) with little or no regard for the factors that limit predictive accuracy. Thus, people express great confidence in the prediction that a person is a librarian when given a description of his personality which matches the stereotype of librarians, even if the description is scanty, unreliable, or out- dated. The unwarranted confidence which is produced by a good fit between the predicted outcome and the input information may be called the illusion of validity. This illusion persists even when the judge is aware of the factors that limit the accuracy of his predic- tions. It is a common observation that psychologists who conduct selection interviews often experience considerable confidence in their predictions, even when they know of the vast literature that shows selection interviews to be
  • 82. highly fallible. The continued reliance on the clinical interview for selection, despite repeated demonstrations of its inadequacy, amply attests to the strength of this effect. The internal consistency of a pattern of inputs is a major determinant of one's confidence in predictions based on these inputs. For example, people express more confidence in predicting the final grade-point average of a student whose first-year record consists entirely of B's than in predicting the grade- point average of a student whose first- year record includes many A's and C's. Highly consistent patterns are most often observed when the input vari- ables are highly redundant or correlated. Hence, people tend to have great con- fidence in predictions based on redun- dant input variables. However, an elementary result in the statistics of cor- relation asserts that, given input vari- ables of stated validity, a prediction based on several such inputs can achieve higher accuracy when they are independent of each other than when they are redundant or correlated. Thus, redundancy among inputs decreases accuracy even as it increases confidence, and people are often confident in pre- dictions that are quite likely to be off the mark (1).