SlideShare a Scribd company logo
1 of 46
Top School in Ghaziabad 
By: 
school.edhole.com
Franco Donzelli 
Topics in the History of Equilibrium Analysis 
Lesson 1 
On the Notion of Neoclassical 
Equilibrium: Walras, Pareto and 
the Stationary Equilibrium Approach 
Ph.D. Program in Economics 
University of York 
February-March 2008 
school.edhole.com
Neoclassical equilibrium 1 
 The “neoclassical” or “marginalistic revolution” is conventionally traced 
back to three works published at the beginning of the 1870s: 
W. S. Jevons, The Theory of Political Economy, 1871 
C. Menger, Grundsätze der Volkswirtschaftslehre, 1871 
L. Walras, Eléments d’économie politique pure, 1874-1877 
 As a matter of fact, these works are much less homogeneous than 
once one used to believe. 
(see Jaffé (1976), “Menger, Jevons and Walras De-homogeneized”, 
Economic Inquiry, 14, pp. 511-524) 
 Yet one can try to single out some common traits: 
 the assumption that each agent (initially, only consumers-traders) 
chooses her/his optimal plan of action by maximizing her/his objective 
function (initially, only utility functions) subject to constraints is common to 
all the three founders; 
 the assumption that the optimally chosen plans must be compatible, 
giving rise to an equilibrium state, is common to Jevons and Walras 
(though not shared by Menger). 
school.edhole.com 
Lesson 1 - Neoclassical Equilibrium 3 Franco Donzelli
Neoclassical equilibrium 2 
 Starting from this (almost) common basis, one can tentatively put 
forward a definition of an abstract concept of neoclassical equilibrium: 
Given an economy, characterized by a specified set of data, a 
neoclassical equilibrium is a state of the economy in which all the 
agents participating in the economy optimally choose their plans of 
action, given the constraints to which they are subjected, and all the 
optimally chosen plans are compatible, both with each other and with 
the external constraints to which the agents are subjected, so that 
they can all be carried out. 
 With reference to a competitive market economy the definition can be 
further specialized: 
 the agents are consumers and producers; 
 commodity prices are the signals that the agents need to take into 
account in solving their optimization programs (since prices enter either 
the constraints to which they are subjected or the objective functions they 
try to maximize). 
school.edhole.com 
Lesson 1 - Neoclassical Equilibrium 4 Franco Donzelli
Neoclassical equilibrium 3 
 One can tentatively define an abstract concept of neoclassical 
competitive equilibrium (not shared by Jevons, however, so that it is 
actually a concept of Walrasian equilibrium): 
Given a competitive economy, characterized by a specified set of data, 
a neoclassical competitive equilibrium is an array of prices, one for 
each commodity existing in the economy, and of plans of action, one 
for each consumer and/or producer participating in the economy, such 
that all the plans of action are both optimally chosen, given the prices 
and the constraints to which the agents are subjected, and compatible, 
both with each other and with the external constraints to which the 
agents are subjected, so that they can all be carried out. 
 Yet, since (at least) the last decade of the Nineteenth century, two 
alternative notions of neoclassical competitive equilibrium have been 
used by different groups of neoclassical economists, coexisting 
thereafter side by side during the first four decades of the twentieth 
century (and beyond): 
 the instantaneous competitive equilibrium notion; 
 the stationary competitive equilibrium notion. school.edhole.com 
Lesson 1 - Neoclassical Equilibrium 5 Franco Donzelli
Instantaneous equilibrium 1 
 The instantaneous equilibrium notion is the equilibrium notion 
eventually adopted by the economists of the Lausanne School, that is, 
by the last Walras, Pareto, and their (very few) immediate followers. 
 Since the late 1920s, such notion started to spread out of the restricted 
circle of the Lausanne School economists, being rediscovered by 
Hayek (1928), (1933), (1937); Lindahl (1929), (1930); Hicks (1933), 
(1939). After the II World War: Arrow-Debreu (1954), Debreu (1959) 
 Walras, in the fourth edition of the Eléments (1900, Lesson 35), and 
Pareto, both in the Cours d’économie politique (1896-97, Vol. II, pp. 
11-13) and in the Manuale di economia politica (1906, pp. 104-105), 
make it clear that the equilibrium concept they intend to adopt is an 
instantaneous equilibrium concept of the temporary type. 
 According to such interpretation, any particular equilibrium of the 
model, corresponding to an admissible specification of the data, should 
be viewed as describing the equilibrium state instantaneously reached 
by the economy at that particular instant (resp., unit period) of its 
history at which the specified data are supposed to prevail. 
school.edhole.com 
Lesson 1 - Neoclassical Equilibrium 6 Franco Donzelli
Instantaneous equilibrium 2 
 Under this interpretation, there is no reason why the data should be 
unchanging over time; on the contrary, one should in general expect 
the data, hence the equilibria, to change as time elapses, for both 
exogenous and endogenous reasons. 
 Hence, under this interpretation, the evolution of the economy over 
time can (must) be described by means of a chronologically ordered 
continuum (resp., sequence) of instantaneous (temporary) 
equilibrium states, differing in general from one another. 
 To refer to this sort of analysis, Walras used the expressions 
“variable or moving equilibrium” or “dynamic point of view”, while 
Pareto (1896-97, Vol. II, pp. 11-13; 1906, pp. 104-105) spoke of the 
“method of successive equilibria”. 
school.edhole.com 
Lesson 1 - Neoclassical Equilibrium 7 Franco Donzelli
Stationary equilibrium 1 
 Since the last decade of the nineteenth century, however, the 
leading economists belonging to all kinds of neoclassical schools, 
with the only exception of the Lausanne school, almost invariably 
started to suggest that their equilibrium models be interpreted as 
stationary equilibrium models. 
 The “neoclassical stationary equilibrium approach” includes such 
theorists as: 
Marshall (1890), Wicksell (1898), (1901), (1906), J.B. Clark (1899), 
(1907), Schumpeter (1911), (1939), Cassel (1918) and (1925), 
Knight (1921), Frisch (1935), Pigou (1935). 
 According to such interpretation, any particular equilibrium of the 
model, corresponding to an admissible specification of the data, 
should be viewed as a stationary state of the economy under 
theoretical investigation. 
school.edhole.com 
Lesson 1 - Neoclassical Equilibrium 8 Franco Donzelli
Stationary equilibrium 2 
 As such, a stationary equilibrium should not be taken to refer to any 
specific instant (resp., period) in the history of the economy, but 
rather to the whole continuum (resp., sequence) of instants (resp., 
periods) over which the data are supposed to be unchanging. 
 But then this interpretation of the equilibrium concept, unlike the 
instantaneous one, forces the theorist to assume the stationarity of 
the data characterizing the economy over time. 
 The adoption, diffusion and eventual supremacy of the stationary 
viewpoint over a period of about forty years are due to a number of 
factors. 
 The most important one has to do with the problem of the “empirical 
justification” of neoclassical equilibrium theory: the equilibrium 
apparatus ought to be “empirically justified” by showing that an 
adjustment mechanism is at work in the economy which is capable 
of driving it towards an equilibrium position. 
school.edhole.com 
Lesson 1 - Neoclassical Equilibrium 9 Franco Donzelli
The evolution of Walras’s thought 1 
 The first to tackle this problem was Walras himself, the founder of the 
general equilibrium approach, to whom both the interpretations of the 
equilibrium notion – the “instantaneous” and the “stationary” one – can 
ultimately be traced. 
 General Equilibrium Theory (GET) was founded by Walras in 1874-77: 
 “Principe d’une théorie mathématique de l’échange” (1874) 
 “Equations de l’échange” (1876) 
 “Equations de la production” (1876) 
 “Equations del la capitalisation” (1877) 
 GET was further developed by Walras over the various editions of the 
Eléments d’économie politique pure: 
 1st edition 1874-77 
 2nd edition 1889 
 3rd edition 1896 
 4th edition 1900 
school.edhole.com 
Lesson 1 - Neoclassical Equilibrium 10 Franco Donzelli
The evolution of Walras’s thought 2 
 In the four mémoires written in the period 1874-77, as well as in the 
four editions of the Eléments d’économie politique pure published 
over the period 1874-1900, Walras developed four nested 
equilibrium models: 
 the models of exchange, production, and capital formation have 
been there since the four mémoires and the 1st edition of the 
Eléments (1874-77); 
 the model of circulation and money was only introduced in the 4th 
edition (1900). 
 The models are nested in the sense that each encompasses the 
previous one (if any). 
school.edhole.com 
Lesson 1 - Neoclassical Equilibrium 11 Franco Donzelli
Walras’s two solution concepts 
 For each of the four models Walras defines two solution concepts: 
the “theoretical” or “mathematical” or even “scientific” solution, on 
the one hand, and the “empirical” or “practical” solution, on the 
other. 
 The “theoretical” solution is the solution of a system of ordinary 
algebraic equations describing the “static” equilibrium conditions 
appropriate to the model concerned: 
e.g., in the exchange model, the “static” equations are the market-clearing 
equations. 
 The “empirical” solution is the (stationary) solution of a system of 
functional equations describing the “dynamic” adjustment process 
appropriate to the model concerned, called by Walras the 
tâtonnement process: 
e.g., in the exchange model, the equations are (incompletely 
formalized) difference equations, embodying the well-known 
Walrasian price-adjustment rule, later also called the “auctioneer’s 
rule” or the “law of supply and demand”. 
school.edhole.com 
Lesson 1 - Neoclassical Equilibrium 12 Franco Donzelli
Walras’s “empirical” solution 
 According to Walras, the system of functional equations describing 
the tâtonnement process mimics (with some idealization, forced by 
analytical reasons) the adjustment process concretely realized by 
the competitive market mechanism: 
this explains why this solution is called “empirical”. 
 Walras never fully formalized the dynamical system and 
consequently never solved it analytically: yet, this deficiency was 
immaterial for Walras, since – according to him – the solution is 
directly “found” by the market. 
 The stationary state to which the dynamic adjustment process 
“certainly” (or at least “probably”) converges is assumed to coincide 
with the “theoretical” solution of the static system of equations. 
 As a consequence of this assumed coincidence, the “theoretical” 
solution acquires an “empirical” content as well, though only 
indirectly. 
school.edhole.com 
Lesson 1 - Neoclassical Equilibrium 13 Franco Donzelli
Walras’s “theoretical” solution 1 
 The static system of equations, unlike the dynamic one, was fully 
formalized by Walras (even if Walras’s formalization does not meet 
contemporary standards of rigor). 
 Can the static system be analytically solved? 
 Two partially conflicting answers were provided by Walras. 
 In Walras’s first theoretical essay (“Principe…”, 1874), the answer is 
apparently positive: 
“A priori, this problem is evidently solvable, at least in principle, by 
means of the mathematical method, as it is actually solvable on the 
market, by means of the empirical method of the rise and fall in 
prices. So far, we have supposed the buyers and sellers to be 
personally present on the market concerned. Yet the presence of 
these traders is not necessary: should they pass their orders to 
some agents, the market will be made by the latter. […] 
school.edhole.com 
Lesson 1 - Neoclassical Equilibrium 14 Franco Donzelli
Walras’s “theoretical” solution 2 
[continued] 
“But, from a theoretical point of view, is the presence of agents more 
necessary than that of the traders themselves? By no means. These 
agents are the sheer executors of orders written on block-notes: if, 
instead of participating in an auction, they hand over their block-notes 
to a calculator, this calculator will determine the equilibrium 
price not certainly so quickly, but without fail more rigorously than 
what could be done by means of the mechanism of the rise and fall 
in prices. We are such calculator: our demand curves represent the 
orders of the traders. Should one give us all the necessary time, we 
must be able to mathematically determine our equilibrium prices.” 
(Walras,1993, p. 37; my translation, italics added) 
school.edhole.com 
Lesson 1 - Neoclassical Equilibrium 15 Franco Donzelli
Walras’s “theoretical” solution 3 
« A priori, ce problème est évidemment soluble, du moins en 
principe, par le procédé mathématique, comme il est soluble, en fait, 
sur le marché, par le procédé empirique de la hausse et de la 
baisse. Sur notre marché, nous avons supposé les acheteurs et les 
vendeurs en présence les uns des autres; mais la présence des ces 
échangeurs n’est pas nécessaire: qu’ils donnent leurs ordres à des 
agents, le marché ce tiendra entre ces derniers. […] Mais, 
théoriquement, la présence des agents est-elle plus nécessaire que 
celle des échangeurs eux-mêmes? Pas le moins du monde. Ces 
agents sont les exécuteurs purs et simples d’ordres inscrits sur des 
carnets: qu’au lieu de faire la criée, ils donnent ces carnets à un 
calculateur, et ce calculateur déterminera le prix d'équilibre non pas 
certes aussi rapidement, mais à coup sûr plus rigoureusement que 
cela ne pourrait se faire par le mécanisme de la hausse et de la 
baisse. Nous sommes ce calculateur ; nos courbes de demande 
représentent les ordres des échangeurs ; on nous donne tout le 
temps nécessaire ; nous devons pouvoir déterminer 
mathématiquement nos prix d’équilibre.» (Walras, 1874, p. 37; 
italics added) 
school.edhole.com 
Lesson 1 - Neoclassical Equilibrium 16 Franco Donzelli
Walras’s “theoretical” solution 4 
 But in the Ist edition of the Eléments (1874-77), published just a few 
months later, Walras is much more cautious: 
“We are now in a position to see clearly what the mechanism of 
market competition is. It is the practical solution, reached through a 
rise or fall in prices, of the same problem of exchange to which we 
have just given a theoretical and mathematical solution; but it must 
be understood that we do not have the slightest idea of substituting 
one solution for the other. The rapidity and reliability of the practical 
solution leave no room for improvement. 
It is a matter of daily experience that even in big markets where 
there are neither brokers nor auctioneers, the current equilibrium 
price is determined within a few minutes, and considerable 
quantities of merchandise are exchanged at that price within half or 
three quarters of an hour. 
In fact the theoretical solution would be absolutely impracticable in 
almost every case.” 
school.edhole.com 
Lesson 1 - Neoclassical Equilibrium 17 Franco Donzelli
Walras’s “theoretical” solution 5 
[continued] 
“On the other hand, it is not a valid objection against our method to 
speak of the difficulty of deriving [empirical] curves or equations of 
exchange. 
Whether there is any advantage to be found in constructing all or 
part of either the demand or the offer curve of a given commodity in 
certain cases, and whether it is possible or impossible to do so, are 
questions on which we reserve judgement entirely. 
For the moment, we are examining the problem of exchange in 
general, and the [abstract] conception, pure and simple, of curves of 
exchange is sufficient and at the same time indispensable.” 
(Walras, 1954, p. 106; Jaffé’s translation) 
 Walras is ambiguous about: 
 the very possibility of numerically or analytically specifying the 
“data” (parameters, functions, relations) of the static system; 
 the solvability of the static system, which however appears to be 
“absolutely impracticable in almost every case” 
school.edhole.com 
Lesson 1 - Neoclassical Equilibrium 18 Franco Donzelli
Walras’s “theoretical” solution 6 
 « On voit clairement à présent ce qu'est le mécanisme de la 
concurrence sur le marché; c'est la solution pratique, et par hausse 
et baisse des prix, du problème de l'échange dont nous avons fourni 
la solution théorique et mathématique. On doit comprendre d'ailleurs 
que notre intention n'est aucunement de substituer une solution à 
l'autre. La solution pratique est d'une rapidité et d'une sûreté qui ne 
laissent rien à désirer. 
On peut voir, sur de grands marchés fonctionnant même sans 
courtiers ni crieurs, le prix courant d'équilibre se déterminer en 
quelques minutes, et des quantités considérables de marchandise 
s'échanger à ce prix en deux ou trois quarts d'heure. Au contraire, la 
solution théorique serait, dans presque tous les cas, absolument 
impraticable. » 
(Walras, 1988, p. 93; italics added) 
school.edhole.com 
Lesson 1 - Neoclassical Equilibrium 19 Franco Donzelli
Walras’s view of the equilibration process 1 
 Once again, the solvability of the static system is immaterial for 
Walras, as long as the “theoretical” solution coincides with the 
“empirical” solution “found” by the market. 
 This requirement severely constrains the nature of the tâtonnement 
process: for such process must not change the “data” of the 
economy. 
 Yet this requirement conflicts with Walras’s original (pre-analytic) 
vision of the equilibration process, which is very “realistic”. 
 The tâtonnement process (in both exchange and production) is 
initially viewed by Walras as an observable disequilibrium process in 
“real” time, leading to a stationary equilibrium state. 
 In the first edition of the Eléments Walras apparently does not rule 
out the occurrence of observable disequilibrium trades and certainly 
allows for the occurrence of observable disequilibrium production. 
school.edhole.com 
Lesson 1 - Neoclassical Equilibrium 20 Franco Donzelli
Walras’s view of the equilibration process 2 
 Right at the beginning of Lesson 5 of the Eléments, one finds a long 
illustrative passage, where the functioning of the market for “3 per 
cent French Rentes” is described in detail (an almost identical 
illustration, referring however to the “corn market”, had already been 
introduced in Walras’s first mémoire, “Principe…”): 
“Let us take, for example, trading in 3 per cent French Rentes on the 
Paris Stock Exchange and confine our attention to these operations 
alone. The three per cent, as they are called, are quoted at 60 
francs. [...] 
We shall apply the term effective offer to any offer made, in this way, 
of a definite amount of a commodity at a definite price. [...] We shall 
apply the term effective demand to any such demand for a definite 
amount of a commodity at a definite price. 
We have now to make three suppositions according as the demand 
is equal to, greater than, or less than the offer. 
school.edhole.com 
Lesson 1 - Neoclassical Equilibrium 21 Franco Donzelli
Walras’s view of the equilibration process 3 
[continued] 
“First supposition. The quantity demanded at 60 francs is equal to 
the quantity offered at this same price. [...] The rate of 60 francs is 
maintained. The market is in a stationary state or equilibrium. 
Second supposition. The brokers with orders to buy can no longer 
find brokers with orders to sell. [...] Brokers [...] make bids at 60 
francs 05 centimes. They raise the market price. 
Third supposition. Brokers with orders to sell can no longer find 
brokers with orders to buy. [...] Brokers [...] make offers at 59 francs 
95 centimes. They lower the price.” 
(Walras, 1954, pp. 84-85) 
 As can be seen, Walras is apparently willing to allow the traders 
(“brokers”) not only to change the price, contrary to the standard 
competitive assumption of price-taking behavior, but actually to 
trade out of equilibrium. 
school.edhole.com 
Lesson 1 - Neoclassical Equilibrium 22 Franco Donzelli
Walras’s view of the equilibration process 4 
 But: 
 no theory of observable disequilibrium behavior is available; 
 observable disequilibrium behavior would generally entail some 
changes in the “data”; 
 a stationary equilibrium model cannot be easily applied to a 
changing (“progressive”) economy. 
 In 1883 the mathematician Bertrand criticizes Walras’s assumptions 
concerning the trading process, maintaining that observable 
disequilibrium transactions would make the equilibrium indeterminate. 
 As a matter of fact, there is more than that: not only would the 
equilibrium be indeterminate, but the whole equilibration process 
would become theoretically intractable, for Walras can provide no 
theory of observable disequilibrium trade. 
 Yet Bertrand does not raise this further point, nor is he bothered by 
the limitations of the stationary equilibrium assumption. 
school.edhole.com 
Lesson 1 - Neoclassical Equilibrium 23 Franco Donzelli
Walras’s view of the equilibration process 5 
 Walras reacts to Bertrand’s critique first in a footnote in an obscure 
paper published in 1885, and then in the second edition of the 
Eléments (1889). 
 In both these writings Walras makes an explicit “no-trade-out-of-equilibrium- 
assumption”, turning the tâtonnement process in the 
“exchange model” into a purely virtual process in “logical time”, which 
takes just a single instant of “real” time to carry its effects through. 
 Specifically, in the second edition of the Eléments (1889), Walras 
changes the securities example, by adding the expressions: 
 "Exchange takes place" in the case of market equilibrium; 
 "Theoretically, trading should come to a halt" and "Trading stops" 
in the case of excess demand and excess supply, respectively. 
 In view of this, the equilibrium of the exchange model should be 
conceived as instantaneously arrived at – what Walras explicitly 
recognizes in his 1885 paper, when he says that the overall 
equilibrium exchanges will take place “à un instant donné”. 
school.edhole.com 
Lesson 1 - Neoclassical Equilibrium 24 Franco Donzelli
Walras’s view of the equilibration process 6 
 Yet Walras does not change the expression “stationary state or 
equilibrium”, appearing in the first edition of the Eléments. 
 Moreover he sticks to the original assumption that observable 
disequilibrium production can occur in the economy. 
 In order to confront a number of obvious analytical difficulties raised 
by the latter assumption, in the “production model” he assumes the 
data of the economy (quantities of available services) to remain 
unchanged over time: thereby the “production model” becomes a 
stationary equilibrium model of a pure-flow economy. 
 Hence in the second edition of the Eléments there coexist two 
alternative interpretations of the tâtonnement process: a virtual one 
in “logical time”, in the “exchange model”, and an observable one in 
“real time”, in the “production model”. 
school.edhole.com 
Lesson 1 - Neoclassical Equilibrium 25 Franco Donzelli
Walras’s view of the equilibration process 7 
 The interpretation of the equilibrium concept is ambiguous: sometimes it 
appears to be instantaneous (as it happens in Walras 1885), while on 
other occasions it appears to be stationary (occasionally in Walras 1889). 
 Walras is unable to solve the dilemma in the third edition of the Eléments 
(1896). 
 Only in the fourth edition of the Eléments (1900), by making the so-called 
“hypothèse des bons”, Walras eventually generalizes to all models and 
activities the interpretation of the tâtonnement already adopted with 
reference to the exchange model only. 
 According to this interpretation, the tâtonnement becomes a purely virtual 
process, taking place in a sort of “logical time”, to be distinguished from 
the “real time” over which the economy evolves, and capable of bringing 
about its full effects without consuming any amount of “real time”. 
 At the same time, Walras drops any surviving reference to a stationary 
equilibrium concept, adopting instead an instantaneous equilibrium notion 
(of the temporary type) as his only tool of analysis. 
school.edhole.com 
Lesson 1 - Neoclassical Equilibrium 26 Franco Donzelli
Walras’s view of the equilibration process 8 
 In the fourth edition of the Eléments (1900) Walras writes as follows: 
« Au moyen de l'hypothèse des bons, on peut distinguer nettement, 
surtout si l'on les suppose successives, les trois phases suivantes: 
1° La phase des tâtonnements préliminaires en vue de l'établissement 
de l'équilibre en principe; 
2° La phase statique de l'établissement effectif ab ovo de l'équilibre 
relatif à la livraison des services producteurs et des produits pendant 
la période de temps considérée, aux conditions convenues, sans 
changements dans les données du problème; 
3° Une phase dynamique de trouble continuel de l'équilibre par des 
changements dans ces données et de rétablissement continuel de 
l'équilibre ainsi troublé. En conséquence de ces définitions, il doit être 
bien entendu que les capitaux neufs, fixes ou circulants, qui seront 
livrés pendant la seconde phase [...], ne fonctionneront que dans la 
troisième phase, constituant ainsi un premier changement dans les 
données du problème. » (Walras, [1900] 1988, pp. 447, 449, 4-5) 
school.edhole.com 
Lesson 1 - Neoclassical Equilibrium 27 Franco Donzelli
Walras’s view of the equilibration process 9 
 Hence Walras’s revised assumptions concerning the tâtonnement process: 
 exchange model: “no-trade-out-of-equilibrium assumption” (1885, 
1889); 
 models of production, capital formation, circulation and money: 
“hypothèse des bons” (1900). 
 Walras’s final conception: the tâtonnement process is eventually viewed as 
a virtual, unobservable disequilibrium process in “logical” time, leading to 
an instantaneous equilibrium state (of the “temporary” type) 
 The paradoxical outcome of Walras’s theoretical revisions is the following: 
 the explanatory power and empirical content of Walras’s final version of 
his general equilibrium theory crucially rest on the convergence of the 
tâtonnement process; 
 but the process itself can only be described by means of a highly 
unrealistic, vaguely defined model, whose very stability, never formally 
discussed by Walras, is nothing more than a tenet of faith. 
school.edhole.com 
Lesson 1 - Neoclassical Equilibrium 28 Franco Donzelli
Walras on the epistemological status of GET 1 
 The change in Walras’s perspective is essentially due to his attempt 
of overcoming the theoretical difficulties related to the assumption of 
an observable disequilibrium approach in “real time” and the 
associated stationary equilibrium notion. 
 Yet, even if the reasons for Walras’s change of mind are essentially 
theoretical, he can also allege some motives of an empirical 
character. 
 The purely virtual interpretation of the tâtonnement is an empirically 
acceptable approximation of the real-world equilibration process 
since, according to Walras, the latter process is very effective and 
extraordinarily quick (see quotations pp. 18-20 above). 
 By the same token, Walras is led to justify the theoretical use of an 
instantaneous equilibrium notion (of the temporary type) as an 
empirically acceptable approximation. 
school.edhole.com 
Lesson 1 - Neoclassical Equilibrium 29 Franco Donzelli
Walras on the epistemological status of GET 2 
 What is then the relation between theory and reality according to 
Walras? 
 Walras’s answer is given in Lesson 35 “The continuous market” 
(Walras, 1954, 380): 
“Finally, in order to come still more closely to reality, we must drop the 
hypothesis of an annual market period and adopt in its place the 
hypothesis of a continuous market. Thus we pass from the static to 
the dynamic state. […] 
Such is the continuous market, which is perpetually tending towards 
equilibrium without ever attaining it, because the market has no other 
way of approaching equilibrium except by groping, and, before the 
goal is reached, it has to renew its efforts and start over again, all the 
basic data of the problem […] having changed in the meantime.” 
 Yet the description of such continuous disequilibrium process by 
means of a sequence of temporary equilibria is justified by Walras as 
a reasonable approximation, also in view of the assumed rapidity of 
the equilibration process (“the current equilibrium price is determined 
within a few minutes”). school.edhole.com 
Lesson 1 - Neoclassical Equilibrium 30 Franco Donzelli
Pareto on statics and dynamics 1 
 Vilfredo Pareto, Walras’s successor on the economics chair of the 
University of Lausanne, took over the general equilibrium approach 
from Walras and further developed it chiefly in the following writings: 
Cours d’économie politique (1896-97) 
Manuale di economia politica (1906) 
Manuel d’économie politique (1909) 
 Did Pareto tackle the analytical and epistemological questions left 
open by Walras? Was he able to solve them? To what extent? 
 In the Cours (1896-97, Vol. II, 23-24) Pareto sided with Walras in the 
latter’s controversy with Edgeworth over the theory of the 
tâtonnement, but his defense of Walras’s theoretical construct was 
purely formal. 
 Even if Pareto’s knowledge of dynamical systems theory and 
rational mechanics was much better than Walras’s, he never tried to 
formalize the latter’s theory of the tâtonnement and he eventually 
dropped it in the Manuale. 
school.edhole.com 
Lesson 1 - Neoclassical Equilibrium 31 Franco Donzelli
Pareto on statics and dynamics 2 
 The reason for this is that Pareto, unlike Walras, was aware, at least 
to a certain extent, that the relationship between statics, or 
equilibrium theory, and dynamics is not so simple in economics as it 
is in rational mechanics. 
 While in mechanics the so-called d’Alembert principle allows one to 
switch from the static equations defining the equilibrium position of a 
material system to the dynamic equations defining its motion, no such 
easy passage is possible in economics. 
 As Pareto explained in the Cours … (1896-97, pp. 11-12; my 
translation): 
“Society may then be regarded as being in a state of equilibrium, and 
a stable one. To tell the truth, it is a question here of dynamic, rather 
than static, equilibrium, as the entire society is driven by a general 
movement that slowly changes it. Such movement is generally 
designated by the term evolution.” 
school.edhole.com 
Lesson 1 - Neoclassical Equilibrium 32 Franco Donzelli
Pareto on statics and dynamics 3 
[continued] 
“In mechanics the d’Alembert principle allows us to study the dynamic 
state of a system completely. In political economy, for the time being, 
we can only catch a glimpse of a similar principle. In the social 
science, even this vague notion is wanting. In both these latter 
sciences, we are compelled to substitute the analysis of a sequence of 
static equilibria for the analysis of dynamic equilibrium. 
To give a somewhat rough but expressive idea of the matter, suppose 
that a man in a sleigh slides down a slope at the same time as another 
man steps down the same slope, stopping at every step. The two men 
start simultaneously from the top, constantly proceed together, and 
arrive simultaneously at the foot of the hill. Hence, by and large, their 
motion is approximately the same. But the motion of the man in the 
sleigh is a continuous one: its study involves a problem of dynamics. 
The motion of the man stepping down on foot represents a sequence 
of successive positions of equilibrium: he proceeds from one to the 
next discontinuously. It is precisely such a sequence of equilibrium 
positions that we can study in political economy.” 
school.edhole.com 
Lesson 1 - Neoclassical Equilibrium 33 Franco Donzelli
Pareto on statics and dynamics 4 
« Pour donner une idée assez grossière, mais expressive de la chose, 
supposons qu’un homme qui est dans un traîneau, glisse sur une 
pente. Un autre homme descend à pied la même pente, en s’arrêtant à 
chaque pas. Les deux hommes partent en même temps du sommet, 
voyagent constamment en compagnie, et arrivent en même temps en 
bas de la pente. En gros, leur mouvement est donc à peu près le 
même. Mais le mouvement de l’homme qui est dans le traîneau, est un 
mouvement continu, son étude constitue un problème de dynamique. 
Le mouvement de l’homme descendant à pied, représente une suite 
de positions successives d’équilibre. Il passe de l’une à l’autre, d’une 
manière discontinue. C’est précisément une suite semblable de 
positions d’équilibre que nous pouvons étudier en économie 
politique. » 
(Pareto, 1987, p. 10, par. 587). 
school.edhole.com 
Lesson 1 - Neoclassical Equilibrium 34 Franco Donzelli
Pareto on the meaning of equilibrium 1 
 Pareto ended up with adopting a methodological position which is 
similar to that embraced by the last Walras (that of Lesson 35 “The 
continuous market”), the only difference being that, for Pareto, only 
statics (i.e., equilibrium theory) matters, while the theory of the 
tâtonnement is immaterial. 
 Equilibrium theory, and specifically the “method of successive 
equilibria”, provides a first approximation to an ever changing 
economy. 
 As Pareto wrote in the Cours … (1896-97, Vol. I, p. 58; my translation): 
“In reality, the equilibrium is never reached since, in so far as one tries 
to approach it, it continuously changes as the technical and economic 
conditions of production change. The real state is then a state of 
persistent oscillations around a central equilibrium point, which itself 
drifts away.” 
school.edhole.com 
Lesson 1 - Neoclassical Equilibrium 35 Franco Donzelli
Pareto on the meaning of equilibrium 2 
 As to the insolvability of the static system of equations, Pareto was 
apparently much sharper than Walras. 
 In the Manuale … (1906) Pareto wrote (1927, pp. 233-234): 
“It may be mentioned here that this determination has by no means the 
purpose to arrive at a numerical calculation of prices. Let us make the 
most favourable assumption for such a calculation, let us assume that 
we have triumphed over all the difficulties of finding the data of the 
problem and that we know the ophélimités of all the different 
commodities for each individual, and all the conditions of production of 
all commodities, etc. This is already an absurd hypothesis to make. 
Yet it is not sufficient to make the solution of the problem possible. 
We have seen that in the case of 100 persons and 700 commodities 
there will be 70,699 conditions (actually a great number of 
circumstances that we have so far neglected will further increase that 
number); we will therefore have to solve a system of 70,699 equations. 
school.edhole.com 
Lesson 1 - Neoclassical Equilibrium 36 Franco Donzelli
Pareto on the meaning of equilibrium 3 
 [continued] 
This exceeds practically the power of algebraic analysis, and this is even 
more true if one contemplates the fabulous number of equations which 
one obtains for a population of forty million people and several thousand 
commodities. 
In this case the rôles would be changed: it would not be mathematics 
which would assist political economy, but political economy would assist 
mathematics. In other words, if one really could know all these 
equations, the only means to solve them which is available to human 
powers is to observe the practical solution given by the market.” 
 In the above passage Pareto underlines two sorts of practical difficulties: 
 difficulties related to the collection of a huge number of individual 
data; 
 computational difficulties due to the size of the equational system. 
school.edhole.com 
Lesson 1 - Neoclassical Equilibrium 37 Franco Donzelli
Pareto on the epistemological status of GET 1 
 What is then, for Pareto, the epistemological status of GET? 
 In the Cours … (1896-97, Vol. II, 8-9, my translation) Pareto 
distinguished three sorts of scientific explanations and corresponding 
types of theories: 
“Let us consider, in general, certain phenomena A, B, C. Our 
knowledge concerning their mutual dependence may pass through 
three successive stages. α) We may only know that such dependence 
exists […]. β) We may have an idea of the links existing among A, B, 
C, […]. In other words, we may know the directions of the changes 
arising in B, C, D … as a consequence of a certain change in A. γ) 
Finally, we can not only know the directions of such changes, but also 
exactly calculate their magnitudes. When we reach such point, our 
knowledge is complete and perfect. 
As regards the motions of [bodies belonging to] the solar system, 
astronomy has reached stage (γ) […]. In general, if the numerical data 
are enough, mechanics allows us to reach the degree of knowledge (γ) 
as far as a material system is concerned. If numerical data are lacking, 
it leads us at least to degree (β). 
school.edhole.com 
Lesson 1 - Neoclassical Equilibrium 38 Franco Donzelli
Pareto on the epistemological status of GET 2 
[continued] 
Before the new theories were discovered, political economy had 
stopped at degree (α) […] The new theories have raised political 
economy to degree (β). The complete system of equilibrium equations 
not only helps to emphasize the mutual dependence of economic 
phenomena, but is also of use to enlighten us about the directions of 
the changes in certain elements when we make other elements 
change. Still more: such equations show us the way that will allow us 
to climb to level (γ), as soon as statistics is able to provide the data 
necessary to this end.” 
 Then, after all, Pareto did not rule out the possibility that, in the more or 
less distant future, General Equilibrium Theory can be used to obtain 
some sort of “complete and perfect knowledge” of the economic 
phenomena (though not deterministic, but only statistical in nature). 
 Yet, neither in the Manuale … (1906), nor in the Manuel … (1909), 
such sort of statistical approach to GET was ever concretely employed 
or even exemplified. 
school.edhole.com 
Lesson 1 - Neoclassical Equilibrium 39 Franco Donzelli
Summary of Walras’s and Pareto’s stances on GET 1 
 The epistemological status of GET is highly ambiguous from beginning 
to end. 
 For Walras GET is an empirical theory, but its empirical content is 
made to depend on a theoretical construct, the tâtonnement, whose 
empirical content is itself controversial. 
 Starting from a highly realistic interpretation of the tâtonnement, 
Walras progressively realizes the theoretical difficulties connected with 
such interpretation, slowly turning the tâtonnement into a less and less 
realistic construct. 
 In the end, by means of the no-trade-out-of-equilibrium-assumption 
(1885, 1889) in the exchange model and the “hypothèse des bons” in 
the models of production, capital formation, and circulation and money 
(1900), the tâtonnement becomes a purely virtual, durationless 
process in “logical” time, instantaneously leading to an instantaneous 
equilibrium at every instant of “real” time. 
school.edhole.com 
Lesson 1 - Neoclassical Equilibrium 40 Franco Donzelli
Summary of Walras’s and Pareto’s stances on GET 2 
 Pareto drops the theory of the tâtonnement altogether, focusing on the 
static notion of equilibrium exclusively. 
 Pareto takes over Walras’s notion of an instantaneous (mobile) 
equilibrium, explicitly maintaining that the study of successive positions 
of static equilibrium over time is the only method that economics, 
unlike mechanics, can make use of. 
 For Pareto it is “absurd” to deem that the system of equations defining 
a static equilibrium state can be numerically solved, chiefly owing to 
practical difficulties of data collection and computation. 
 Yet such system, though analytically unsolvable, still retains a sort of 
intermediate explanatory power, as a first approximation to a highly 
complex world. 
 For Pareto (1896-97), if sufficient statistical data were collected, the 
use of GET to produce quantitative predictions of a statistical kind 
could not be ruled out in the future. Yet, in (1906) and (1909) Pareto 
did not produce any significant instance of such a use of GET. 
school.edhole.com 
Lesson 1 - Neoclassical Equilibrium 41 Franco Donzelli
The stationary equilibrium approach 1 
 Walras’s and Pareto’s ultimate empirical justification for using an 
instantaneous equilibrium concept rested on their confidence in the 
speed and effectiveness of the real-world equilibration processes. 
 Yet this confidence was not shared by most neoclassical economists 
of the first generations: on the contrary, they were convinced that 
the adjustment processes at work in real-world markets take a lot of 
time to carry their effects through. 
 However a time-consuming process can hopefully approach a well-defined 
equilibrium position only if the data of the economy remain 
unchanged over time. 
 This means that the use of the equilibrium apparatus can apparently 
be “empirically justified” only if the economy under investigation is 
assumed to be characterized by an unchanging set of data. 
school.edhole.com 
Lesson 1 - Neoclassical Equilibrium 42 Franco Donzelli
The stationary equilibrium approach 2 
 In conclusion, the chief reasons behind the swift diffusion and almost 
general adoption of the stationary interpretation of the equilibrium 
concept around the turn of the Nineteenth century and in the 
following years were: 
 the concern with the empirical relevance of equilibrium analysis; 
 the belief (or the suspicion) that any real-world adjustment 
process cannot but be slow and time-consuming. 
 These, on the other hand, are also the main reasons why a stationary 
interpretation of the equilibrium concept had survived so long in 
Walras’s own writings, up until the fourth edition of the Eléments 
(1900), occasionally sneaking in Pareto’s writings as well. 
 Another reason, at least as far as Walras and Pareto are concerned, 
was their desire to imitate the physical sciences, and rational 
mechanics specifically: for in those sciences there is no distinction 
between “real” and “logical” time and any equilibrium necessarily is a 
stationary state of some sort (in “real” time). 
school.edhole.com 
Lesson 1 - Neoclassical Equilibrium 43 Franco Donzelli
The stationary equilibrium approach 3 
 Yet, the stationary equilibrium approach, if consistently employed, 
has a very limited scope. 
 The assumption of stationarity of the data, which it is obliged to 
make, forces it to rule out all sorts of activities which might cause an 
endogenous change in the data. 
 In a general equilibrium model, i.e., a model analyzing a number of 
interconnected markets, this means to rule out all intertemporal 
activities, such as savings, investment, credit, dealings in durables, 
dealings in money or financial assets, etc. 
 The only kind of economy which can be consistently examined 
within this approach is a pure-flow economy, i.e., an economy 
where the only kinds of commodities produced, consumed and 
traded are services (by definition non-durables) and non-durable 
consumers’ goods. 
school.edhole.com 
Lesson 1 - Neoclassical Equilibrium 44 Franco Donzelli
The stationary equilibrium approach 4 
 In such an economy the agents have no way to connect with one 
another, by means of their economic activities, the time periods over 
which the economy evolves: for this economy is an “isolated-period” 
economy (Hicks). 
 This is the essence, e.g., of the so-called “Walras-Cassel model”, the 
model of a pure flow-economy that Cassel ((1918), (1925)) derived 
from reinterpreting Walras’s original “production model”. 
 Another example is Wicksell’s “model of a-capitalistic production” 
((1901), (1906)) or Schumpeter’s “circular flow model” ((1911), 
(1939)). 
 A different way to preserve the assumption of stationarity of the data 
is Marshall’s adoption of the coeteris paribus clause, with its related 
restriction of the analysis to the partial equilibrium framework of an 
isolated market (some special supplementary assumptions on the 
agents’ characteristics, such as the “constant marginal utility of 
money” assumption, need also to be made). 
school.edhole.com 
Lesson 1 - Neoclassical Equilibrium 45 Franco Donzelli
The stationary equilibrium approach 5 
 When the strict boundaries of the approach are not respected, as 
when “capital” in some sense is incorporated into the stationary 
equilibrium models, inconsistencies necessarily ensue. 
 This happens, in particular, with Wicksell’s “model of capitalistic 
production” ((1901), (1906)), J.B. Clark’s “model of a static economy” 
((1899), (1907)), Schumpeter’s “model of capitalistic development” 
((1911), (1939)), Cassel’s “model of a uniformly progressing 
economy” ((1918), (1925)). 
 The controversies on the theory of capital, raging in the inter-War 
period (1920s and 1930s), and again, much later, in the 1960s and 
1970s, arise precisely from these attempts to preserve a stationary 
equilibrium interpretation of the “neoclassical” equilibrium concept in 
models where such interpretation is logically inconsistent: 
 for, due to the existence of “capital”, the time periods over which the 
economy evolves are not isolated from one another and the 
economy is not a pure-flow economy. 
school.edhole.com 
Lesson 1 - Neoclassical Equilibrium 46 Franco Donzelli

More Related Content

Similar to Top school in ghaziabad

Logotipo seminario de la luiss (ingles) i parte
Logotipo seminario de la luiss (ingles) i parteLogotipo seminario de la luiss (ingles) i parte
Logotipo seminario de la luiss (ingles) i parteGregory Lombardo
 
The analogy of economics principles and physics theory
The analogy of economics principles and physics theoryThe analogy of economics principles and physics theory
The analogy of economics principles and physics theoryAlexander Decker
 
Smelser Neil J., Swedberg Richard. - The Sociological Perspective on the Econ...
Smelser Neil J., Swedberg Richard. - The Sociological Perspective on the Econ...Smelser Neil J., Swedberg Richard. - The Sociological Perspective on the Econ...
Smelser Neil J., Swedberg Richard. - The Sociological Perspective on the Econ...zddglygt
 
(Akerlof 2003) george a. akerlof, “writing the ‘the market for 'lemons’
(Akerlof 2003) george a. akerlof, “writing the ‘the market for 'lemons’(Akerlof 2003) george a. akerlof, “writing the ‘the market for 'lemons’
(Akerlof 2003) george a. akerlof, “writing the ‘the market for 'lemons’Adam Higdon
 
Economics and accounting a comparison between philosophical
Economics and accounting a comparison between philosophical Economics and accounting a comparison between philosophical
Economics and accounting a comparison between philosophical accounting2010
 
CONTRIBUTIONS OF ALFRED MARSHALL TO THE FIELD OF ECONOMICS
CONTRIBUTIONS OF ALFRED MARSHALL TO THE FIELD OF ECONOMICSCONTRIBUTIONS OF ALFRED MARSHALL TO THE FIELD OF ECONOMICS
CONTRIBUTIONS OF ALFRED MARSHALL TO THE FIELD OF ECONOMICSRejoitJames
 
Science and advances of the knowledge in economics
Science and advances of the knowledge in economicsScience and advances of the knowledge in economics
Science and advances of the knowledge in economicsFernando Alcoforado
 
The crisis of the formula of liberal democracy
The crisis of the formula of liberal democracyThe crisis of the formula of liberal democracy
The crisis of the formula of liberal democracyRemigiuszRosicki
 
The Future of Post Keynesian Economics
The Future of Post Keynesian EconomicsThe Future of Post Keynesian Economics
The Future of Post Keynesian Economicspkconference
 
Sustainable Economic Systems.pptx
Sustainable Economic Systems.pptxSustainable Economic Systems.pptx
Sustainable Economic Systems.pptxkenjiekris
 
Nature and scopes of Economics
Nature and scopes of EconomicsNature and scopes of Economics
Nature and scopes of EconomicsANKUR AGRAWAL
 
FASHION AND GLOBALIZATION
FASHION AND GLOBALIZATIONFASHION AND GLOBALIZATION
FASHION AND GLOBALIZATIONsuzi smith
 

Similar to Top school in ghaziabad (20)

Logotipo seminario de la luiss (ingles) i parte
Logotipo seminario de la luiss (ingles) i parteLogotipo seminario de la luiss (ingles) i parte
Logotipo seminario de la luiss (ingles) i parte
 
Walras ref168
Walras ref168Walras ref168
Walras ref168
 
The analogy of economics principles and physics theory
The analogy of economics principles and physics theoryThe analogy of economics principles and physics theory
The analogy of economics principles and physics theory
 
Smelser Neil J., Swedberg Richard. - The Sociological Perspective on the Econ...
Smelser Neil J., Swedberg Richard. - The Sociological Perspective on the Econ...Smelser Neil J., Swedberg Richard. - The Sociological Perspective on the Econ...
Smelser Neil J., Swedberg Richard. - The Sociological Perspective on the Econ...
 
(Akerlof 2003) george a. akerlof, “writing the ‘the market for 'lemons’
(Akerlof 2003) george a. akerlof, “writing the ‘the market for 'lemons’(Akerlof 2003) george a. akerlof, “writing the ‘the market for 'lemons’
(Akerlof 2003) george a. akerlof, “writing the ‘the market for 'lemons’
 
Economics and accounting a comparison between philosophical
Economics and accounting a comparison between philosophical Economics and accounting a comparison between philosophical
Economics and accounting a comparison between philosophical
 
CONTRIBUTIONS OF ALFRED MARSHALL TO THE FIELD OF ECONOMICS
CONTRIBUTIONS OF ALFRED MARSHALL TO THE FIELD OF ECONOMICSCONTRIBUTIONS OF ALFRED MARSHALL TO THE FIELD OF ECONOMICS
CONTRIBUTIONS OF ALFRED MARSHALL TO THE FIELD OF ECONOMICS
 
Science and advances of the knowledge in economics
Science and advances of the knowledge in economicsScience and advances of the knowledge in economics
Science and advances of the knowledge in economics
 
Economics
EconomicsEconomics
Economics
 
Famous economists presentation
Famous economists presentationFamous economists presentation
Famous economists presentation
 
Innovation systems 101-lecture-5
Innovation systems 101-lecture-5Innovation systems 101-lecture-5
Innovation systems 101-lecture-5
 
The crisis of the formula of liberal democracy
The crisis of the formula of liberal democracyThe crisis of the formula of liberal democracy
The crisis of the formula of liberal democracy
 
The Future of Post Keynesian Economics
The Future of Post Keynesian EconomicsThe Future of Post Keynesian Economics
The Future of Post Keynesian Economics
 
The dynamics of revolutions
The dynamics of revolutionsThe dynamics of revolutions
The dynamics of revolutions
 
Economics for entrepreneurs 2
Economics for entrepreneurs 2Economics for entrepreneurs 2
Economics for entrepreneurs 2
 
Economics for entrepreneurs 2
Economics for entrepreneurs 2Economics for entrepreneurs 2
Economics for entrepreneurs 2
 
Sustainable Economic Systems.pptx
Sustainable Economic Systems.pptxSustainable Economic Systems.pptx
Sustainable Economic Systems.pptx
 
Economics
EconomicsEconomics
Economics
 
Nature and scopes of Economics
Nature and scopes of EconomicsNature and scopes of Economics
Nature and scopes of Economics
 
FASHION AND GLOBALIZATION
FASHION AND GLOBALIZATIONFASHION AND GLOBALIZATION
FASHION AND GLOBALIZATION
 

More from Edhole.com

Chartered accountant in dwarka
Chartered accountant in dwarkaChartered accountant in dwarka
Chartered accountant in dwarkaEdhole.com
 
Ca firm in dwarka
Ca firm in dwarkaCa firm in dwarka
Ca firm in dwarkaEdhole.com
 
Website development company surat
Website development company suratWebsite development company surat
Website development company suratEdhole.com
 
Website designing company in surat
Website designing company in suratWebsite designing company in surat
Website designing company in suratEdhole.com
 
Website dsigning company in india
Website dsigning company in indiaWebsite dsigning company in india
Website dsigning company in indiaEdhole.com
 
Website designing company in delhi
Website designing company in delhiWebsite designing company in delhi
Website designing company in delhiEdhole.com
 
Chartered accountant in dwarka
Chartered accountant in dwarkaChartered accountant in dwarka
Chartered accountant in dwarkaEdhole.com
 
Ca firm in dwarka
Ca firm in dwarkaCa firm in dwarka
Ca firm in dwarkaEdhole.com
 
Website development company surat
Website development company suratWebsite development company surat
Website development company suratEdhole.com
 
Website designing company in surat
Website designing company in suratWebsite designing company in surat
Website designing company in suratEdhole.com
 
Website designing company in india
Website designing company in indiaWebsite designing company in india
Website designing company in indiaEdhole.com
 
Website designing company in delhi
Website designing company in delhiWebsite designing company in delhi
Website designing company in delhiEdhole.com
 
Website designing company in mumbai
Website designing company in mumbaiWebsite designing company in mumbai
Website designing company in mumbaiEdhole.com
 
Website development company surat
Website development company suratWebsite development company surat
Website development company suratEdhole.com
 
Website desinging company in surat
Website desinging company in suratWebsite desinging company in surat
Website desinging company in suratEdhole.com
 
Website designing company in india
Website designing company in indiaWebsite designing company in india
Website designing company in indiaEdhole.com
 

More from Edhole.com (20)

Ca in patna
Ca in patnaCa in patna
Ca in patna
 
Chartered accountant in dwarka
Chartered accountant in dwarkaChartered accountant in dwarka
Chartered accountant in dwarka
 
Ca in dwarka
Ca in dwarkaCa in dwarka
Ca in dwarka
 
Ca firm in dwarka
Ca firm in dwarkaCa firm in dwarka
Ca firm in dwarka
 
Website development company surat
Website development company suratWebsite development company surat
Website development company surat
 
Website designing company in surat
Website designing company in suratWebsite designing company in surat
Website designing company in surat
 
Website dsigning company in india
Website dsigning company in indiaWebsite dsigning company in india
Website dsigning company in india
 
Website designing company in delhi
Website designing company in delhiWebsite designing company in delhi
Website designing company in delhi
 
Ca in patna
Ca in patnaCa in patna
Ca in patna
 
Chartered accountant in dwarka
Chartered accountant in dwarkaChartered accountant in dwarka
Chartered accountant in dwarka
 
Ca firm in dwarka
Ca firm in dwarkaCa firm in dwarka
Ca firm in dwarka
 
Ca in dwarka
Ca in dwarkaCa in dwarka
Ca in dwarka
 
Website development company surat
Website development company suratWebsite development company surat
Website development company surat
 
Website designing company in surat
Website designing company in suratWebsite designing company in surat
Website designing company in surat
 
Website designing company in india
Website designing company in indiaWebsite designing company in india
Website designing company in india
 
Website designing company in delhi
Website designing company in delhiWebsite designing company in delhi
Website designing company in delhi
 
Website designing company in mumbai
Website designing company in mumbaiWebsite designing company in mumbai
Website designing company in mumbai
 
Website development company surat
Website development company suratWebsite development company surat
Website development company surat
 
Website desinging company in surat
Website desinging company in suratWebsite desinging company in surat
Website desinging company in surat
 
Website designing company in india
Website designing company in indiaWebsite designing company in india
Website designing company in india
 

Recently uploaded

Web & Social Media Analytics Previous Year Question Paper.pdf
Web & Social Media Analytics Previous Year Question Paper.pdfWeb & Social Media Analytics Previous Year Question Paper.pdf
Web & Social Media Analytics Previous Year Question Paper.pdfJayanti Pande
 
Arihant handbook biology for class 11 .pdf
Arihant handbook biology for class 11 .pdfArihant handbook biology for class 11 .pdf
Arihant handbook biology for class 11 .pdfchloefrazer622
 
SOCIAL AND HISTORICAL CONTEXT - LFTVD.pptx
SOCIAL AND HISTORICAL CONTEXT - LFTVD.pptxSOCIAL AND HISTORICAL CONTEXT - LFTVD.pptx
SOCIAL AND HISTORICAL CONTEXT - LFTVD.pptxiammrhaywood
 
9548086042 for call girls in Indira Nagar with room service
9548086042  for call girls in Indira Nagar  with room service9548086042  for call girls in Indira Nagar  with room service
9548086042 for call girls in Indira Nagar with room servicediscovermytutordmt
 
Introduction to Nonprofit Accounting: The Basics
Introduction to Nonprofit Accounting: The BasicsIntroduction to Nonprofit Accounting: The Basics
Introduction to Nonprofit Accounting: The BasicsTechSoup
 
BAG TECHNIQUE Bag technique-a tool making use of public health bag through wh...
BAG TECHNIQUE Bag technique-a tool making use of public health bag through wh...BAG TECHNIQUE Bag technique-a tool making use of public health bag through wh...
BAG TECHNIQUE Bag technique-a tool making use of public health bag through wh...Sapna Thakur
 
Software Engineering Methodologies (overview)
Software Engineering Methodologies (overview)Software Engineering Methodologies (overview)
Software Engineering Methodologies (overview)eniolaolutunde
 
Accessible design: Minimum effort, maximum impact
Accessible design: Minimum effort, maximum impactAccessible design: Minimum effort, maximum impact
Accessible design: Minimum effort, maximum impactdawncurless
 
Explore beautiful and ugly buildings. Mathematics helps us create beautiful d...
Explore beautiful and ugly buildings. Mathematics helps us create beautiful d...Explore beautiful and ugly buildings. Mathematics helps us create beautiful d...
Explore beautiful and ugly buildings. Mathematics helps us create beautiful d...christianmathematics
 
Sports & Fitness Value Added Course FY..
Sports & Fitness Value Added Course FY..Sports & Fitness Value Added Course FY..
Sports & Fitness Value Added Course FY..Disha Kariya
 
Measures of Central Tendency: Mean, Median and Mode
Measures of Central Tendency: Mean, Median and ModeMeasures of Central Tendency: Mean, Median and Mode
Measures of Central Tendency: Mean, Median and ModeThiyagu K
 
Interactive Powerpoint_How to Master effective communication
Interactive Powerpoint_How to Master effective communicationInteractive Powerpoint_How to Master effective communication
Interactive Powerpoint_How to Master effective communicationnomboosow
 
Student login on Anyboli platform.helpin
Student login on Anyboli platform.helpinStudent login on Anyboli platform.helpin
Student login on Anyboli platform.helpinRaunakKeshri1
 
Unit-IV- Pharma. Marketing Channels.pptx
Unit-IV- Pharma. Marketing Channels.pptxUnit-IV- Pharma. Marketing Channels.pptx
Unit-IV- Pharma. Marketing Channels.pptxVishalSingh1417
 
Sanyam Choudhary Chemistry practical.pdf
Sanyam Choudhary Chemistry practical.pdfSanyam Choudhary Chemistry practical.pdf
Sanyam Choudhary Chemistry practical.pdfsanyamsingh5019
 
Advanced Views - Calendar View in Odoo 17
Advanced Views - Calendar View in Odoo 17Advanced Views - Calendar View in Odoo 17
Advanced Views - Calendar View in Odoo 17Celine George
 
Beyond the EU: DORA and NIS 2 Directive's Global Impact
Beyond the EU: DORA and NIS 2 Directive's Global ImpactBeyond the EU: DORA and NIS 2 Directive's Global Impact
Beyond the EU: DORA and NIS 2 Directive's Global ImpactPECB
 

Recently uploaded (20)

Web & Social Media Analytics Previous Year Question Paper.pdf
Web & Social Media Analytics Previous Year Question Paper.pdfWeb & Social Media Analytics Previous Year Question Paper.pdf
Web & Social Media Analytics Previous Year Question Paper.pdf
 
Arihant handbook biology for class 11 .pdf
Arihant handbook biology for class 11 .pdfArihant handbook biology for class 11 .pdf
Arihant handbook biology for class 11 .pdf
 
INDIA QUIZ 2024 RLAC DELHI UNIVERSITY.pptx
INDIA QUIZ 2024 RLAC DELHI UNIVERSITY.pptxINDIA QUIZ 2024 RLAC DELHI UNIVERSITY.pptx
INDIA QUIZ 2024 RLAC DELHI UNIVERSITY.pptx
 
SOCIAL AND HISTORICAL CONTEXT - LFTVD.pptx
SOCIAL AND HISTORICAL CONTEXT - LFTVD.pptxSOCIAL AND HISTORICAL CONTEXT - LFTVD.pptx
SOCIAL AND HISTORICAL CONTEXT - LFTVD.pptx
 
9548086042 for call girls in Indira Nagar with room service
9548086042  for call girls in Indira Nagar  with room service9548086042  for call girls in Indira Nagar  with room service
9548086042 for call girls in Indira Nagar with room service
 
Introduction to Nonprofit Accounting: The Basics
Introduction to Nonprofit Accounting: The BasicsIntroduction to Nonprofit Accounting: The Basics
Introduction to Nonprofit Accounting: The Basics
 
BAG TECHNIQUE Bag technique-a tool making use of public health bag through wh...
BAG TECHNIQUE Bag technique-a tool making use of public health bag through wh...BAG TECHNIQUE Bag technique-a tool making use of public health bag through wh...
BAG TECHNIQUE Bag technique-a tool making use of public health bag through wh...
 
Software Engineering Methodologies (overview)
Software Engineering Methodologies (overview)Software Engineering Methodologies (overview)
Software Engineering Methodologies (overview)
 
Accessible design: Minimum effort, maximum impact
Accessible design: Minimum effort, maximum impactAccessible design: Minimum effort, maximum impact
Accessible design: Minimum effort, maximum impact
 
Explore beautiful and ugly buildings. Mathematics helps us create beautiful d...
Explore beautiful and ugly buildings. Mathematics helps us create beautiful d...Explore beautiful and ugly buildings. Mathematics helps us create beautiful d...
Explore beautiful and ugly buildings. Mathematics helps us create beautiful d...
 
Sports & Fitness Value Added Course FY..
Sports & Fitness Value Added Course FY..Sports & Fitness Value Added Course FY..
Sports & Fitness Value Added Course FY..
 
Measures of Central Tendency: Mean, Median and Mode
Measures of Central Tendency: Mean, Median and ModeMeasures of Central Tendency: Mean, Median and Mode
Measures of Central Tendency: Mean, Median and Mode
 
Interactive Powerpoint_How to Master effective communication
Interactive Powerpoint_How to Master effective communicationInteractive Powerpoint_How to Master effective communication
Interactive Powerpoint_How to Master effective communication
 
Student login on Anyboli platform.helpin
Student login on Anyboli platform.helpinStudent login on Anyboli platform.helpin
Student login on Anyboli platform.helpin
 
Unit-IV- Pharma. Marketing Channels.pptx
Unit-IV- Pharma. Marketing Channels.pptxUnit-IV- Pharma. Marketing Channels.pptx
Unit-IV- Pharma. Marketing Channels.pptx
 
Sanyam Choudhary Chemistry practical.pdf
Sanyam Choudhary Chemistry practical.pdfSanyam Choudhary Chemistry practical.pdf
Sanyam Choudhary Chemistry practical.pdf
 
Advanced Views - Calendar View in Odoo 17
Advanced Views - Calendar View in Odoo 17Advanced Views - Calendar View in Odoo 17
Advanced Views - Calendar View in Odoo 17
 
Beyond the EU: DORA and NIS 2 Directive's Global Impact
Beyond the EU: DORA and NIS 2 Directive's Global ImpactBeyond the EU: DORA and NIS 2 Directive's Global Impact
Beyond the EU: DORA and NIS 2 Directive's Global Impact
 
Código Creativo y Arte de Software | Unidad 1
Código Creativo y Arte de Software | Unidad 1Código Creativo y Arte de Software | Unidad 1
Código Creativo y Arte de Software | Unidad 1
 
Mattingly "AI & Prompt Design: Structured Data, Assistants, & RAG"
Mattingly "AI & Prompt Design: Structured Data, Assistants, & RAG"Mattingly "AI & Prompt Design: Structured Data, Assistants, & RAG"
Mattingly "AI & Prompt Design: Structured Data, Assistants, & RAG"
 

Top school in ghaziabad

  • 1. Top School in Ghaziabad By: school.edhole.com
  • 2. Franco Donzelli Topics in the History of Equilibrium Analysis Lesson 1 On the Notion of Neoclassical Equilibrium: Walras, Pareto and the Stationary Equilibrium Approach Ph.D. Program in Economics University of York February-March 2008 school.edhole.com
  • 3. Neoclassical equilibrium 1  The “neoclassical” or “marginalistic revolution” is conventionally traced back to three works published at the beginning of the 1870s: W. S. Jevons, The Theory of Political Economy, 1871 C. Menger, Grundsätze der Volkswirtschaftslehre, 1871 L. Walras, Eléments d’économie politique pure, 1874-1877  As a matter of fact, these works are much less homogeneous than once one used to believe. (see Jaffé (1976), “Menger, Jevons and Walras De-homogeneized”, Economic Inquiry, 14, pp. 511-524)  Yet one can try to single out some common traits:  the assumption that each agent (initially, only consumers-traders) chooses her/his optimal plan of action by maximizing her/his objective function (initially, only utility functions) subject to constraints is common to all the three founders;  the assumption that the optimally chosen plans must be compatible, giving rise to an equilibrium state, is common to Jevons and Walras (though not shared by Menger). school.edhole.com Lesson 1 - Neoclassical Equilibrium 3 Franco Donzelli
  • 4. Neoclassical equilibrium 2  Starting from this (almost) common basis, one can tentatively put forward a definition of an abstract concept of neoclassical equilibrium: Given an economy, characterized by a specified set of data, a neoclassical equilibrium is a state of the economy in which all the agents participating in the economy optimally choose their plans of action, given the constraints to which they are subjected, and all the optimally chosen plans are compatible, both with each other and with the external constraints to which the agents are subjected, so that they can all be carried out.  With reference to a competitive market economy the definition can be further specialized:  the agents are consumers and producers;  commodity prices are the signals that the agents need to take into account in solving their optimization programs (since prices enter either the constraints to which they are subjected or the objective functions they try to maximize). school.edhole.com Lesson 1 - Neoclassical Equilibrium 4 Franco Donzelli
  • 5. Neoclassical equilibrium 3  One can tentatively define an abstract concept of neoclassical competitive equilibrium (not shared by Jevons, however, so that it is actually a concept of Walrasian equilibrium): Given a competitive economy, characterized by a specified set of data, a neoclassical competitive equilibrium is an array of prices, one for each commodity existing in the economy, and of plans of action, one for each consumer and/or producer participating in the economy, such that all the plans of action are both optimally chosen, given the prices and the constraints to which the agents are subjected, and compatible, both with each other and with the external constraints to which the agents are subjected, so that they can all be carried out.  Yet, since (at least) the last decade of the Nineteenth century, two alternative notions of neoclassical competitive equilibrium have been used by different groups of neoclassical economists, coexisting thereafter side by side during the first four decades of the twentieth century (and beyond):  the instantaneous competitive equilibrium notion;  the stationary competitive equilibrium notion. school.edhole.com Lesson 1 - Neoclassical Equilibrium 5 Franco Donzelli
  • 6. Instantaneous equilibrium 1  The instantaneous equilibrium notion is the equilibrium notion eventually adopted by the economists of the Lausanne School, that is, by the last Walras, Pareto, and their (very few) immediate followers.  Since the late 1920s, such notion started to spread out of the restricted circle of the Lausanne School economists, being rediscovered by Hayek (1928), (1933), (1937); Lindahl (1929), (1930); Hicks (1933), (1939). After the II World War: Arrow-Debreu (1954), Debreu (1959)  Walras, in the fourth edition of the Eléments (1900, Lesson 35), and Pareto, both in the Cours d’économie politique (1896-97, Vol. II, pp. 11-13) and in the Manuale di economia politica (1906, pp. 104-105), make it clear that the equilibrium concept they intend to adopt is an instantaneous equilibrium concept of the temporary type.  According to such interpretation, any particular equilibrium of the model, corresponding to an admissible specification of the data, should be viewed as describing the equilibrium state instantaneously reached by the economy at that particular instant (resp., unit period) of its history at which the specified data are supposed to prevail. school.edhole.com Lesson 1 - Neoclassical Equilibrium 6 Franco Donzelli
  • 7. Instantaneous equilibrium 2  Under this interpretation, there is no reason why the data should be unchanging over time; on the contrary, one should in general expect the data, hence the equilibria, to change as time elapses, for both exogenous and endogenous reasons.  Hence, under this interpretation, the evolution of the economy over time can (must) be described by means of a chronologically ordered continuum (resp., sequence) of instantaneous (temporary) equilibrium states, differing in general from one another.  To refer to this sort of analysis, Walras used the expressions “variable or moving equilibrium” or “dynamic point of view”, while Pareto (1896-97, Vol. II, pp. 11-13; 1906, pp. 104-105) spoke of the “method of successive equilibria”. school.edhole.com Lesson 1 - Neoclassical Equilibrium 7 Franco Donzelli
  • 8. Stationary equilibrium 1  Since the last decade of the nineteenth century, however, the leading economists belonging to all kinds of neoclassical schools, with the only exception of the Lausanne school, almost invariably started to suggest that their equilibrium models be interpreted as stationary equilibrium models.  The “neoclassical stationary equilibrium approach” includes such theorists as: Marshall (1890), Wicksell (1898), (1901), (1906), J.B. Clark (1899), (1907), Schumpeter (1911), (1939), Cassel (1918) and (1925), Knight (1921), Frisch (1935), Pigou (1935).  According to such interpretation, any particular equilibrium of the model, corresponding to an admissible specification of the data, should be viewed as a stationary state of the economy under theoretical investigation. school.edhole.com Lesson 1 - Neoclassical Equilibrium 8 Franco Donzelli
  • 9. Stationary equilibrium 2  As such, a stationary equilibrium should not be taken to refer to any specific instant (resp., period) in the history of the economy, but rather to the whole continuum (resp., sequence) of instants (resp., periods) over which the data are supposed to be unchanging.  But then this interpretation of the equilibrium concept, unlike the instantaneous one, forces the theorist to assume the stationarity of the data characterizing the economy over time.  The adoption, diffusion and eventual supremacy of the stationary viewpoint over a period of about forty years are due to a number of factors.  The most important one has to do with the problem of the “empirical justification” of neoclassical equilibrium theory: the equilibrium apparatus ought to be “empirically justified” by showing that an adjustment mechanism is at work in the economy which is capable of driving it towards an equilibrium position. school.edhole.com Lesson 1 - Neoclassical Equilibrium 9 Franco Donzelli
  • 10. The evolution of Walras’s thought 1  The first to tackle this problem was Walras himself, the founder of the general equilibrium approach, to whom both the interpretations of the equilibrium notion – the “instantaneous” and the “stationary” one – can ultimately be traced.  General Equilibrium Theory (GET) was founded by Walras in 1874-77:  “Principe d’une théorie mathématique de l’échange” (1874)  “Equations de l’échange” (1876)  “Equations de la production” (1876)  “Equations del la capitalisation” (1877)  GET was further developed by Walras over the various editions of the Eléments d’économie politique pure:  1st edition 1874-77  2nd edition 1889  3rd edition 1896  4th edition 1900 school.edhole.com Lesson 1 - Neoclassical Equilibrium 10 Franco Donzelli
  • 11. The evolution of Walras’s thought 2  In the four mémoires written in the period 1874-77, as well as in the four editions of the Eléments d’économie politique pure published over the period 1874-1900, Walras developed four nested equilibrium models:  the models of exchange, production, and capital formation have been there since the four mémoires and the 1st edition of the Eléments (1874-77);  the model of circulation and money was only introduced in the 4th edition (1900).  The models are nested in the sense that each encompasses the previous one (if any). school.edhole.com Lesson 1 - Neoclassical Equilibrium 11 Franco Donzelli
  • 12. Walras’s two solution concepts  For each of the four models Walras defines two solution concepts: the “theoretical” or “mathematical” or even “scientific” solution, on the one hand, and the “empirical” or “practical” solution, on the other.  The “theoretical” solution is the solution of a system of ordinary algebraic equations describing the “static” equilibrium conditions appropriate to the model concerned: e.g., in the exchange model, the “static” equations are the market-clearing equations.  The “empirical” solution is the (stationary) solution of a system of functional equations describing the “dynamic” adjustment process appropriate to the model concerned, called by Walras the tâtonnement process: e.g., in the exchange model, the equations are (incompletely formalized) difference equations, embodying the well-known Walrasian price-adjustment rule, later also called the “auctioneer’s rule” or the “law of supply and demand”. school.edhole.com Lesson 1 - Neoclassical Equilibrium 12 Franco Donzelli
  • 13. Walras’s “empirical” solution  According to Walras, the system of functional equations describing the tâtonnement process mimics (with some idealization, forced by analytical reasons) the adjustment process concretely realized by the competitive market mechanism: this explains why this solution is called “empirical”.  Walras never fully formalized the dynamical system and consequently never solved it analytically: yet, this deficiency was immaterial for Walras, since – according to him – the solution is directly “found” by the market.  The stationary state to which the dynamic adjustment process “certainly” (or at least “probably”) converges is assumed to coincide with the “theoretical” solution of the static system of equations.  As a consequence of this assumed coincidence, the “theoretical” solution acquires an “empirical” content as well, though only indirectly. school.edhole.com Lesson 1 - Neoclassical Equilibrium 13 Franco Donzelli
  • 14. Walras’s “theoretical” solution 1  The static system of equations, unlike the dynamic one, was fully formalized by Walras (even if Walras’s formalization does not meet contemporary standards of rigor).  Can the static system be analytically solved?  Two partially conflicting answers were provided by Walras.  In Walras’s first theoretical essay (“Principe…”, 1874), the answer is apparently positive: “A priori, this problem is evidently solvable, at least in principle, by means of the mathematical method, as it is actually solvable on the market, by means of the empirical method of the rise and fall in prices. So far, we have supposed the buyers and sellers to be personally present on the market concerned. Yet the presence of these traders is not necessary: should they pass their orders to some agents, the market will be made by the latter. […] school.edhole.com Lesson 1 - Neoclassical Equilibrium 14 Franco Donzelli
  • 15. Walras’s “theoretical” solution 2 [continued] “But, from a theoretical point of view, is the presence of agents more necessary than that of the traders themselves? By no means. These agents are the sheer executors of orders written on block-notes: if, instead of participating in an auction, they hand over their block-notes to a calculator, this calculator will determine the equilibrium price not certainly so quickly, but without fail more rigorously than what could be done by means of the mechanism of the rise and fall in prices. We are such calculator: our demand curves represent the orders of the traders. Should one give us all the necessary time, we must be able to mathematically determine our equilibrium prices.” (Walras,1993, p. 37; my translation, italics added) school.edhole.com Lesson 1 - Neoclassical Equilibrium 15 Franco Donzelli
  • 16. Walras’s “theoretical” solution 3 « A priori, ce problème est évidemment soluble, du moins en principe, par le procédé mathématique, comme il est soluble, en fait, sur le marché, par le procédé empirique de la hausse et de la baisse. Sur notre marché, nous avons supposé les acheteurs et les vendeurs en présence les uns des autres; mais la présence des ces échangeurs n’est pas nécessaire: qu’ils donnent leurs ordres à des agents, le marché ce tiendra entre ces derniers. […] Mais, théoriquement, la présence des agents est-elle plus nécessaire que celle des échangeurs eux-mêmes? Pas le moins du monde. Ces agents sont les exécuteurs purs et simples d’ordres inscrits sur des carnets: qu’au lieu de faire la criée, ils donnent ces carnets à un calculateur, et ce calculateur déterminera le prix d'équilibre non pas certes aussi rapidement, mais à coup sûr plus rigoureusement que cela ne pourrait se faire par le mécanisme de la hausse et de la baisse. Nous sommes ce calculateur ; nos courbes de demande représentent les ordres des échangeurs ; on nous donne tout le temps nécessaire ; nous devons pouvoir déterminer mathématiquement nos prix d’équilibre.» (Walras, 1874, p. 37; italics added) school.edhole.com Lesson 1 - Neoclassical Equilibrium 16 Franco Donzelli
  • 17. Walras’s “theoretical” solution 4  But in the Ist edition of the Eléments (1874-77), published just a few months later, Walras is much more cautious: “We are now in a position to see clearly what the mechanism of market competition is. It is the practical solution, reached through a rise or fall in prices, of the same problem of exchange to which we have just given a theoretical and mathematical solution; but it must be understood that we do not have the slightest idea of substituting one solution for the other. The rapidity and reliability of the practical solution leave no room for improvement. It is a matter of daily experience that even in big markets where there are neither brokers nor auctioneers, the current equilibrium price is determined within a few minutes, and considerable quantities of merchandise are exchanged at that price within half or three quarters of an hour. In fact the theoretical solution would be absolutely impracticable in almost every case.” school.edhole.com Lesson 1 - Neoclassical Equilibrium 17 Franco Donzelli
  • 18. Walras’s “theoretical” solution 5 [continued] “On the other hand, it is not a valid objection against our method to speak of the difficulty of deriving [empirical] curves or equations of exchange. Whether there is any advantage to be found in constructing all or part of either the demand or the offer curve of a given commodity in certain cases, and whether it is possible or impossible to do so, are questions on which we reserve judgement entirely. For the moment, we are examining the problem of exchange in general, and the [abstract] conception, pure and simple, of curves of exchange is sufficient and at the same time indispensable.” (Walras, 1954, p. 106; Jaffé’s translation)  Walras is ambiguous about:  the very possibility of numerically or analytically specifying the “data” (parameters, functions, relations) of the static system;  the solvability of the static system, which however appears to be “absolutely impracticable in almost every case” school.edhole.com Lesson 1 - Neoclassical Equilibrium 18 Franco Donzelli
  • 19. Walras’s “theoretical” solution 6  « On voit clairement à présent ce qu'est le mécanisme de la concurrence sur le marché; c'est la solution pratique, et par hausse et baisse des prix, du problème de l'échange dont nous avons fourni la solution théorique et mathématique. On doit comprendre d'ailleurs que notre intention n'est aucunement de substituer une solution à l'autre. La solution pratique est d'une rapidité et d'une sûreté qui ne laissent rien à désirer. On peut voir, sur de grands marchés fonctionnant même sans courtiers ni crieurs, le prix courant d'équilibre se déterminer en quelques minutes, et des quantités considérables de marchandise s'échanger à ce prix en deux ou trois quarts d'heure. Au contraire, la solution théorique serait, dans presque tous les cas, absolument impraticable. » (Walras, 1988, p. 93; italics added) school.edhole.com Lesson 1 - Neoclassical Equilibrium 19 Franco Donzelli
  • 20. Walras’s view of the equilibration process 1  Once again, the solvability of the static system is immaterial for Walras, as long as the “theoretical” solution coincides with the “empirical” solution “found” by the market.  This requirement severely constrains the nature of the tâtonnement process: for such process must not change the “data” of the economy.  Yet this requirement conflicts with Walras’s original (pre-analytic) vision of the equilibration process, which is very “realistic”.  The tâtonnement process (in both exchange and production) is initially viewed by Walras as an observable disequilibrium process in “real” time, leading to a stationary equilibrium state.  In the first edition of the Eléments Walras apparently does not rule out the occurrence of observable disequilibrium trades and certainly allows for the occurrence of observable disequilibrium production. school.edhole.com Lesson 1 - Neoclassical Equilibrium 20 Franco Donzelli
  • 21. Walras’s view of the equilibration process 2  Right at the beginning of Lesson 5 of the Eléments, one finds a long illustrative passage, where the functioning of the market for “3 per cent French Rentes” is described in detail (an almost identical illustration, referring however to the “corn market”, had already been introduced in Walras’s first mémoire, “Principe…”): “Let us take, for example, trading in 3 per cent French Rentes on the Paris Stock Exchange and confine our attention to these operations alone. The three per cent, as they are called, are quoted at 60 francs. [...] We shall apply the term effective offer to any offer made, in this way, of a definite amount of a commodity at a definite price. [...] We shall apply the term effective demand to any such demand for a definite amount of a commodity at a definite price. We have now to make three suppositions according as the demand is equal to, greater than, or less than the offer. school.edhole.com Lesson 1 - Neoclassical Equilibrium 21 Franco Donzelli
  • 22. Walras’s view of the equilibration process 3 [continued] “First supposition. The quantity demanded at 60 francs is equal to the quantity offered at this same price. [...] The rate of 60 francs is maintained. The market is in a stationary state or equilibrium. Second supposition. The brokers with orders to buy can no longer find brokers with orders to sell. [...] Brokers [...] make bids at 60 francs 05 centimes. They raise the market price. Third supposition. Brokers with orders to sell can no longer find brokers with orders to buy. [...] Brokers [...] make offers at 59 francs 95 centimes. They lower the price.” (Walras, 1954, pp. 84-85)  As can be seen, Walras is apparently willing to allow the traders (“brokers”) not only to change the price, contrary to the standard competitive assumption of price-taking behavior, but actually to trade out of equilibrium. school.edhole.com Lesson 1 - Neoclassical Equilibrium 22 Franco Donzelli
  • 23. Walras’s view of the equilibration process 4  But:  no theory of observable disequilibrium behavior is available;  observable disequilibrium behavior would generally entail some changes in the “data”;  a stationary equilibrium model cannot be easily applied to a changing (“progressive”) economy.  In 1883 the mathematician Bertrand criticizes Walras’s assumptions concerning the trading process, maintaining that observable disequilibrium transactions would make the equilibrium indeterminate.  As a matter of fact, there is more than that: not only would the equilibrium be indeterminate, but the whole equilibration process would become theoretically intractable, for Walras can provide no theory of observable disequilibrium trade.  Yet Bertrand does not raise this further point, nor is he bothered by the limitations of the stationary equilibrium assumption. school.edhole.com Lesson 1 - Neoclassical Equilibrium 23 Franco Donzelli
  • 24. Walras’s view of the equilibration process 5  Walras reacts to Bertrand’s critique first in a footnote in an obscure paper published in 1885, and then in the second edition of the Eléments (1889).  In both these writings Walras makes an explicit “no-trade-out-of-equilibrium- assumption”, turning the tâtonnement process in the “exchange model” into a purely virtual process in “logical time”, which takes just a single instant of “real” time to carry its effects through.  Specifically, in the second edition of the Eléments (1889), Walras changes the securities example, by adding the expressions:  "Exchange takes place" in the case of market equilibrium;  "Theoretically, trading should come to a halt" and "Trading stops" in the case of excess demand and excess supply, respectively.  In view of this, the equilibrium of the exchange model should be conceived as instantaneously arrived at – what Walras explicitly recognizes in his 1885 paper, when he says that the overall equilibrium exchanges will take place “à un instant donné”. school.edhole.com Lesson 1 - Neoclassical Equilibrium 24 Franco Donzelli
  • 25. Walras’s view of the equilibration process 6  Yet Walras does not change the expression “stationary state or equilibrium”, appearing in the first edition of the Eléments.  Moreover he sticks to the original assumption that observable disequilibrium production can occur in the economy.  In order to confront a number of obvious analytical difficulties raised by the latter assumption, in the “production model” he assumes the data of the economy (quantities of available services) to remain unchanged over time: thereby the “production model” becomes a stationary equilibrium model of a pure-flow economy.  Hence in the second edition of the Eléments there coexist two alternative interpretations of the tâtonnement process: a virtual one in “logical time”, in the “exchange model”, and an observable one in “real time”, in the “production model”. school.edhole.com Lesson 1 - Neoclassical Equilibrium 25 Franco Donzelli
  • 26. Walras’s view of the equilibration process 7  The interpretation of the equilibrium concept is ambiguous: sometimes it appears to be instantaneous (as it happens in Walras 1885), while on other occasions it appears to be stationary (occasionally in Walras 1889).  Walras is unable to solve the dilemma in the third edition of the Eléments (1896).  Only in the fourth edition of the Eléments (1900), by making the so-called “hypothèse des bons”, Walras eventually generalizes to all models and activities the interpretation of the tâtonnement already adopted with reference to the exchange model only.  According to this interpretation, the tâtonnement becomes a purely virtual process, taking place in a sort of “logical time”, to be distinguished from the “real time” over which the economy evolves, and capable of bringing about its full effects without consuming any amount of “real time”.  At the same time, Walras drops any surviving reference to a stationary equilibrium concept, adopting instead an instantaneous equilibrium notion (of the temporary type) as his only tool of analysis. school.edhole.com Lesson 1 - Neoclassical Equilibrium 26 Franco Donzelli
  • 27. Walras’s view of the equilibration process 8  In the fourth edition of the Eléments (1900) Walras writes as follows: « Au moyen de l'hypothèse des bons, on peut distinguer nettement, surtout si l'on les suppose successives, les trois phases suivantes: 1° La phase des tâtonnements préliminaires en vue de l'établissement de l'équilibre en principe; 2° La phase statique de l'établissement effectif ab ovo de l'équilibre relatif à la livraison des services producteurs et des produits pendant la période de temps considérée, aux conditions convenues, sans changements dans les données du problème; 3° Une phase dynamique de trouble continuel de l'équilibre par des changements dans ces données et de rétablissement continuel de l'équilibre ainsi troublé. En conséquence de ces définitions, il doit être bien entendu que les capitaux neufs, fixes ou circulants, qui seront livrés pendant la seconde phase [...], ne fonctionneront que dans la troisième phase, constituant ainsi un premier changement dans les données du problème. » (Walras, [1900] 1988, pp. 447, 449, 4-5) school.edhole.com Lesson 1 - Neoclassical Equilibrium 27 Franco Donzelli
  • 28. Walras’s view of the equilibration process 9  Hence Walras’s revised assumptions concerning the tâtonnement process:  exchange model: “no-trade-out-of-equilibrium assumption” (1885, 1889);  models of production, capital formation, circulation and money: “hypothèse des bons” (1900).  Walras’s final conception: the tâtonnement process is eventually viewed as a virtual, unobservable disequilibrium process in “logical” time, leading to an instantaneous equilibrium state (of the “temporary” type)  The paradoxical outcome of Walras’s theoretical revisions is the following:  the explanatory power and empirical content of Walras’s final version of his general equilibrium theory crucially rest on the convergence of the tâtonnement process;  but the process itself can only be described by means of a highly unrealistic, vaguely defined model, whose very stability, never formally discussed by Walras, is nothing more than a tenet of faith. school.edhole.com Lesson 1 - Neoclassical Equilibrium 28 Franco Donzelli
  • 29. Walras on the epistemological status of GET 1  The change in Walras’s perspective is essentially due to his attempt of overcoming the theoretical difficulties related to the assumption of an observable disequilibrium approach in “real time” and the associated stationary equilibrium notion.  Yet, even if the reasons for Walras’s change of mind are essentially theoretical, he can also allege some motives of an empirical character.  The purely virtual interpretation of the tâtonnement is an empirically acceptable approximation of the real-world equilibration process since, according to Walras, the latter process is very effective and extraordinarily quick (see quotations pp. 18-20 above).  By the same token, Walras is led to justify the theoretical use of an instantaneous equilibrium notion (of the temporary type) as an empirically acceptable approximation. school.edhole.com Lesson 1 - Neoclassical Equilibrium 29 Franco Donzelli
  • 30. Walras on the epistemological status of GET 2  What is then the relation between theory and reality according to Walras?  Walras’s answer is given in Lesson 35 “The continuous market” (Walras, 1954, 380): “Finally, in order to come still more closely to reality, we must drop the hypothesis of an annual market period and adopt in its place the hypothesis of a continuous market. Thus we pass from the static to the dynamic state. […] Such is the continuous market, which is perpetually tending towards equilibrium without ever attaining it, because the market has no other way of approaching equilibrium except by groping, and, before the goal is reached, it has to renew its efforts and start over again, all the basic data of the problem […] having changed in the meantime.”  Yet the description of such continuous disequilibrium process by means of a sequence of temporary equilibria is justified by Walras as a reasonable approximation, also in view of the assumed rapidity of the equilibration process (“the current equilibrium price is determined within a few minutes”). school.edhole.com Lesson 1 - Neoclassical Equilibrium 30 Franco Donzelli
  • 31. Pareto on statics and dynamics 1  Vilfredo Pareto, Walras’s successor on the economics chair of the University of Lausanne, took over the general equilibrium approach from Walras and further developed it chiefly in the following writings: Cours d’économie politique (1896-97) Manuale di economia politica (1906) Manuel d’économie politique (1909)  Did Pareto tackle the analytical and epistemological questions left open by Walras? Was he able to solve them? To what extent?  In the Cours (1896-97, Vol. II, 23-24) Pareto sided with Walras in the latter’s controversy with Edgeworth over the theory of the tâtonnement, but his defense of Walras’s theoretical construct was purely formal.  Even if Pareto’s knowledge of dynamical systems theory and rational mechanics was much better than Walras’s, he never tried to formalize the latter’s theory of the tâtonnement and he eventually dropped it in the Manuale. school.edhole.com Lesson 1 - Neoclassical Equilibrium 31 Franco Donzelli
  • 32. Pareto on statics and dynamics 2  The reason for this is that Pareto, unlike Walras, was aware, at least to a certain extent, that the relationship between statics, or equilibrium theory, and dynamics is not so simple in economics as it is in rational mechanics.  While in mechanics the so-called d’Alembert principle allows one to switch from the static equations defining the equilibrium position of a material system to the dynamic equations defining its motion, no such easy passage is possible in economics.  As Pareto explained in the Cours … (1896-97, pp. 11-12; my translation): “Society may then be regarded as being in a state of equilibrium, and a stable one. To tell the truth, it is a question here of dynamic, rather than static, equilibrium, as the entire society is driven by a general movement that slowly changes it. Such movement is generally designated by the term evolution.” school.edhole.com Lesson 1 - Neoclassical Equilibrium 32 Franco Donzelli
  • 33. Pareto on statics and dynamics 3 [continued] “In mechanics the d’Alembert principle allows us to study the dynamic state of a system completely. In political economy, for the time being, we can only catch a glimpse of a similar principle. In the social science, even this vague notion is wanting. In both these latter sciences, we are compelled to substitute the analysis of a sequence of static equilibria for the analysis of dynamic equilibrium. To give a somewhat rough but expressive idea of the matter, suppose that a man in a sleigh slides down a slope at the same time as another man steps down the same slope, stopping at every step. The two men start simultaneously from the top, constantly proceed together, and arrive simultaneously at the foot of the hill. Hence, by and large, their motion is approximately the same. But the motion of the man in the sleigh is a continuous one: its study involves a problem of dynamics. The motion of the man stepping down on foot represents a sequence of successive positions of equilibrium: he proceeds from one to the next discontinuously. It is precisely such a sequence of equilibrium positions that we can study in political economy.” school.edhole.com Lesson 1 - Neoclassical Equilibrium 33 Franco Donzelli
  • 34. Pareto on statics and dynamics 4 « Pour donner une idée assez grossière, mais expressive de la chose, supposons qu’un homme qui est dans un traîneau, glisse sur une pente. Un autre homme descend à pied la même pente, en s’arrêtant à chaque pas. Les deux hommes partent en même temps du sommet, voyagent constamment en compagnie, et arrivent en même temps en bas de la pente. En gros, leur mouvement est donc à peu près le même. Mais le mouvement de l’homme qui est dans le traîneau, est un mouvement continu, son étude constitue un problème de dynamique. Le mouvement de l’homme descendant à pied, représente une suite de positions successives d’équilibre. Il passe de l’une à l’autre, d’une manière discontinue. C’est précisément une suite semblable de positions d’équilibre que nous pouvons étudier en économie politique. » (Pareto, 1987, p. 10, par. 587). school.edhole.com Lesson 1 - Neoclassical Equilibrium 34 Franco Donzelli
  • 35. Pareto on the meaning of equilibrium 1  Pareto ended up with adopting a methodological position which is similar to that embraced by the last Walras (that of Lesson 35 “The continuous market”), the only difference being that, for Pareto, only statics (i.e., equilibrium theory) matters, while the theory of the tâtonnement is immaterial.  Equilibrium theory, and specifically the “method of successive equilibria”, provides a first approximation to an ever changing economy.  As Pareto wrote in the Cours … (1896-97, Vol. I, p. 58; my translation): “In reality, the equilibrium is never reached since, in so far as one tries to approach it, it continuously changes as the technical and economic conditions of production change. The real state is then a state of persistent oscillations around a central equilibrium point, which itself drifts away.” school.edhole.com Lesson 1 - Neoclassical Equilibrium 35 Franco Donzelli
  • 36. Pareto on the meaning of equilibrium 2  As to the insolvability of the static system of equations, Pareto was apparently much sharper than Walras.  In the Manuale … (1906) Pareto wrote (1927, pp. 233-234): “It may be mentioned here that this determination has by no means the purpose to arrive at a numerical calculation of prices. Let us make the most favourable assumption for such a calculation, let us assume that we have triumphed over all the difficulties of finding the data of the problem and that we know the ophélimités of all the different commodities for each individual, and all the conditions of production of all commodities, etc. This is already an absurd hypothesis to make. Yet it is not sufficient to make the solution of the problem possible. We have seen that in the case of 100 persons and 700 commodities there will be 70,699 conditions (actually a great number of circumstances that we have so far neglected will further increase that number); we will therefore have to solve a system of 70,699 equations. school.edhole.com Lesson 1 - Neoclassical Equilibrium 36 Franco Donzelli
  • 37. Pareto on the meaning of equilibrium 3  [continued] This exceeds practically the power of algebraic analysis, and this is even more true if one contemplates the fabulous number of equations which one obtains for a population of forty million people and several thousand commodities. In this case the rôles would be changed: it would not be mathematics which would assist political economy, but political economy would assist mathematics. In other words, if one really could know all these equations, the only means to solve them which is available to human powers is to observe the practical solution given by the market.”  In the above passage Pareto underlines two sorts of practical difficulties:  difficulties related to the collection of a huge number of individual data;  computational difficulties due to the size of the equational system. school.edhole.com Lesson 1 - Neoclassical Equilibrium 37 Franco Donzelli
  • 38. Pareto on the epistemological status of GET 1  What is then, for Pareto, the epistemological status of GET?  In the Cours … (1896-97, Vol. II, 8-9, my translation) Pareto distinguished three sorts of scientific explanations and corresponding types of theories: “Let us consider, in general, certain phenomena A, B, C. Our knowledge concerning their mutual dependence may pass through three successive stages. α) We may only know that such dependence exists […]. β) We may have an idea of the links existing among A, B, C, […]. In other words, we may know the directions of the changes arising in B, C, D … as a consequence of a certain change in A. γ) Finally, we can not only know the directions of such changes, but also exactly calculate their magnitudes. When we reach such point, our knowledge is complete and perfect. As regards the motions of [bodies belonging to] the solar system, astronomy has reached stage (γ) […]. In general, if the numerical data are enough, mechanics allows us to reach the degree of knowledge (γ) as far as a material system is concerned. If numerical data are lacking, it leads us at least to degree (β). school.edhole.com Lesson 1 - Neoclassical Equilibrium 38 Franco Donzelli
  • 39. Pareto on the epistemological status of GET 2 [continued] Before the new theories were discovered, political economy had stopped at degree (α) […] The new theories have raised political economy to degree (β). The complete system of equilibrium equations not only helps to emphasize the mutual dependence of economic phenomena, but is also of use to enlighten us about the directions of the changes in certain elements when we make other elements change. Still more: such equations show us the way that will allow us to climb to level (γ), as soon as statistics is able to provide the data necessary to this end.”  Then, after all, Pareto did not rule out the possibility that, in the more or less distant future, General Equilibrium Theory can be used to obtain some sort of “complete and perfect knowledge” of the economic phenomena (though not deterministic, but only statistical in nature).  Yet, neither in the Manuale … (1906), nor in the Manuel … (1909), such sort of statistical approach to GET was ever concretely employed or even exemplified. school.edhole.com Lesson 1 - Neoclassical Equilibrium 39 Franco Donzelli
  • 40. Summary of Walras’s and Pareto’s stances on GET 1  The epistemological status of GET is highly ambiguous from beginning to end.  For Walras GET is an empirical theory, but its empirical content is made to depend on a theoretical construct, the tâtonnement, whose empirical content is itself controversial.  Starting from a highly realistic interpretation of the tâtonnement, Walras progressively realizes the theoretical difficulties connected with such interpretation, slowly turning the tâtonnement into a less and less realistic construct.  In the end, by means of the no-trade-out-of-equilibrium-assumption (1885, 1889) in the exchange model and the “hypothèse des bons” in the models of production, capital formation, and circulation and money (1900), the tâtonnement becomes a purely virtual, durationless process in “logical” time, instantaneously leading to an instantaneous equilibrium at every instant of “real” time. school.edhole.com Lesson 1 - Neoclassical Equilibrium 40 Franco Donzelli
  • 41. Summary of Walras’s and Pareto’s stances on GET 2  Pareto drops the theory of the tâtonnement altogether, focusing on the static notion of equilibrium exclusively.  Pareto takes over Walras’s notion of an instantaneous (mobile) equilibrium, explicitly maintaining that the study of successive positions of static equilibrium over time is the only method that economics, unlike mechanics, can make use of.  For Pareto it is “absurd” to deem that the system of equations defining a static equilibrium state can be numerically solved, chiefly owing to practical difficulties of data collection and computation.  Yet such system, though analytically unsolvable, still retains a sort of intermediate explanatory power, as a first approximation to a highly complex world.  For Pareto (1896-97), if sufficient statistical data were collected, the use of GET to produce quantitative predictions of a statistical kind could not be ruled out in the future. Yet, in (1906) and (1909) Pareto did not produce any significant instance of such a use of GET. school.edhole.com Lesson 1 - Neoclassical Equilibrium 41 Franco Donzelli
  • 42. The stationary equilibrium approach 1  Walras’s and Pareto’s ultimate empirical justification for using an instantaneous equilibrium concept rested on their confidence in the speed and effectiveness of the real-world equilibration processes.  Yet this confidence was not shared by most neoclassical economists of the first generations: on the contrary, they were convinced that the adjustment processes at work in real-world markets take a lot of time to carry their effects through.  However a time-consuming process can hopefully approach a well-defined equilibrium position only if the data of the economy remain unchanged over time.  This means that the use of the equilibrium apparatus can apparently be “empirically justified” only if the economy under investigation is assumed to be characterized by an unchanging set of data. school.edhole.com Lesson 1 - Neoclassical Equilibrium 42 Franco Donzelli
  • 43. The stationary equilibrium approach 2  In conclusion, the chief reasons behind the swift diffusion and almost general adoption of the stationary interpretation of the equilibrium concept around the turn of the Nineteenth century and in the following years were:  the concern with the empirical relevance of equilibrium analysis;  the belief (or the suspicion) that any real-world adjustment process cannot but be slow and time-consuming.  These, on the other hand, are also the main reasons why a stationary interpretation of the equilibrium concept had survived so long in Walras’s own writings, up until the fourth edition of the Eléments (1900), occasionally sneaking in Pareto’s writings as well.  Another reason, at least as far as Walras and Pareto are concerned, was their desire to imitate the physical sciences, and rational mechanics specifically: for in those sciences there is no distinction between “real” and “logical” time and any equilibrium necessarily is a stationary state of some sort (in “real” time). school.edhole.com Lesson 1 - Neoclassical Equilibrium 43 Franco Donzelli
  • 44. The stationary equilibrium approach 3  Yet, the stationary equilibrium approach, if consistently employed, has a very limited scope.  The assumption of stationarity of the data, which it is obliged to make, forces it to rule out all sorts of activities which might cause an endogenous change in the data.  In a general equilibrium model, i.e., a model analyzing a number of interconnected markets, this means to rule out all intertemporal activities, such as savings, investment, credit, dealings in durables, dealings in money or financial assets, etc.  The only kind of economy which can be consistently examined within this approach is a pure-flow economy, i.e., an economy where the only kinds of commodities produced, consumed and traded are services (by definition non-durables) and non-durable consumers’ goods. school.edhole.com Lesson 1 - Neoclassical Equilibrium 44 Franco Donzelli
  • 45. The stationary equilibrium approach 4  In such an economy the agents have no way to connect with one another, by means of their economic activities, the time periods over which the economy evolves: for this economy is an “isolated-period” economy (Hicks).  This is the essence, e.g., of the so-called “Walras-Cassel model”, the model of a pure flow-economy that Cassel ((1918), (1925)) derived from reinterpreting Walras’s original “production model”.  Another example is Wicksell’s “model of a-capitalistic production” ((1901), (1906)) or Schumpeter’s “circular flow model” ((1911), (1939)).  A different way to preserve the assumption of stationarity of the data is Marshall’s adoption of the coeteris paribus clause, with its related restriction of the analysis to the partial equilibrium framework of an isolated market (some special supplementary assumptions on the agents’ characteristics, such as the “constant marginal utility of money” assumption, need also to be made). school.edhole.com Lesson 1 - Neoclassical Equilibrium 45 Franco Donzelli
  • 46. The stationary equilibrium approach 5  When the strict boundaries of the approach are not respected, as when “capital” in some sense is incorporated into the stationary equilibrium models, inconsistencies necessarily ensue.  This happens, in particular, with Wicksell’s “model of capitalistic production” ((1901), (1906)), J.B. Clark’s “model of a static economy” ((1899), (1907)), Schumpeter’s “model of capitalistic development” ((1911), (1939)), Cassel’s “model of a uniformly progressing economy” ((1918), (1925)).  The controversies on the theory of capital, raging in the inter-War period (1920s and 1930s), and again, much later, in the 1960s and 1970s, arise precisely from these attempts to preserve a stationary equilibrium interpretation of the “neoclassical” equilibrium concept in models where such interpretation is logically inconsistent:  for, due to the existence of “capital”, the time periods over which the economy evolves are not isolated from one another and the economy is not a pure-flow economy. school.edhole.com Lesson 1 - Neoclassical Equilibrium 46 Franco Donzelli