SlideShare a Scribd company logo
1 of 46
Department of Economics, University at Buffalo Winston Chang
For use by students of my course only. Further distribution is
prohibited.1
Simple Pure Exchange Models
1 Introduction
The price of a good or service observed in a national market,
without foreign trade, is determined
by demand and supply in that nation. On the supply side,
nations generally have different natural
endowments, different factors of production, and different
technologies relevant to the production
of goods and services. These differences result in variations in
production costs. On the demand
side, people have different incomes and tastes, which generate
unique patterns of demand among
nations. Thus, the autarkic prices observed among nations tend
to be different. Once foreign
trade is opened up, goods and services move between nations.
Some questions that come to mind
when considering foreign trade are: Which country exports
which good? What role do autarkic
prices play in determining the direction of trade? What are the
equilibrium terms of trade? Are
there gains from trade? These are some of the basic questions to
be answered in the study of
international economics.
In this chapter, we will consider some simple exchange models
in order to illustrate the deter-
minants of trade. It will be shown that it is the difference in
relative autarkic prices, not money
prices, that causes trade to take place. We will also examine the
determination of the equilibrium
terms of trade and gains from trade with the help of a simple
exchange model, while keeping the
supply of goods fixed.
2 The Determinants of Barter Trades
To illustrate the basic determinants of trade, we consider a very
simple pure exchange model in
which there are two countries, called home (H) and foreign (F),
and two goods, good 1 (G1)
1Copyright c
2009 by Winston Chang. All rights reserved.
1
and good 2 (G2). Goods are already produced so there are no
new production activities in either
country. Before trade is opened up, each good has an autarkic
price in each country. Let the home
country’s variables be represented without an asterisk and
foreign variables with an asterisk. Let
pj be the money price of goodj in H (j = 1;2), measured, say, in
U.S. dollars andp
�
j be the money
price of goodj in F (j = 1;2), measured in British pounds. These
are the money (nominal) prices
observed in the autarkic (no foreign trade) equilibrium. Assume
that there are no impediments to
trade; namely, there are no transport costs or other trading
costs. The markets are competitive,
and the buyers and sellers all face the same prices. How is the
trade pattern determined? Is it
determined by these nominal prices?
To answer both questions, we first consider a barter exchange
economy in which one good is
directly exchanged for the other. Since there are no trading
costs, if the barter exchange ratios
between the two goods in the two countries are different,
gainful arbitrage activities will take place
and trade will occur. A barter exchange ratio is nothing but the
nominalprice ratio . Let p =
p1=p2 which is called "the relative price of G1 (in terms of
G2)" in H. It measuresp units of G2
that are exchanged for one unit of G1. For example, ifp1 = 10
andp2 = 5; thenp = 2, which
means one unit of G1 can be exchanged for two units of G2.
Formally,p1=p2 has the dimension of�
$10
1G1
�
=
�
$5
1G2
�
= 2G2/1G1. The $ element is canceled out in the ratiop1=p2:
Similarly, the relative
price of G2 (in terms of G1) in H is1=p = p2=p1: The foreign
autarkic relative price of G1 in terms
of G2 isp� = p�1=p
�
2:
The following proposition shows that the determinants of trade
are not the nominal autarkic
prices but the relative autarkic prices.
Proposition 1 Barter trade between a pair of goods can gainfully
take place if theautarkic rela-
tive pricesbetween the pair of goods in the two countries are
different. A country will export the
good whose relative autarkic price is cheaper than the other’s,
and both countries can gain from
the trade.
2
Consider the following autarkic price matrix:
2
64 p1 p�1
p2 p
�
2
3
75 =
2
64 1 40
2 10
3
75 : (1)
From this matrix, we know that one unit of G1 in H can be
exchanged for 0.5 units of G2 (p =
1=2 = 0:5); but in the foreign country, one unit of G1 can be
exchanged for four units of G2
(p� = 40=10 = 4): So if a merchant ships one unit of G1 from H
to F, he can exchange that unit for
four units of G2 in F, compared with only 0.5 units of G2 in H.
He will therefore have a gain of 3.5
units of G2. If this gain is more than enough to pay for the
transportation and other transactions
costs, he will gain from the trade and export G1.
Now think of F. Under autarky, a unit of G2 can be exchanged
forp�2=p
�
1 � 1=p� = 10=40 =
0:25 units of G1: If a merchant ships one unit of G2 from F to
H, he can exchange that unit for
p2=p1 = 2=1 = 2 units of G1. He will gain 1.75 units of G1.
Thus, F will export G2. Unequal
relative prices create the opportunity for profitable arbitrage,
and since both countries gain from
this transaction, trade emerges voluntarily.
The above example illustratesa fundamental principle: if, under
autarky,p1=p2 < p
�
1=p
�
2; then
H will export G1, and F will export G2. It is easy to verify that
ifp1=p2 > p
�
1=p
�
2; then the opposite
trade pattern occurs. Thus, wheneverp1=p2 6= p�1=p�2; trade
will take place. Furthermore, both
countries gain from trade.
Note that the relative prices are independent of currency units
used in each country. If H is the
U.S., F is the U.K., and$1 = $1; then the U.K.’s autarkic money
prices in terms of dollars are both
higher than those in the U.S. If trade was thought to be
determined by comparing the money prices,
then the U.K. would not have been able to export any good. It is
theautarkic relative prices that
matter in the determination of the pattern of barter trade, not
thenominal money prices. Since
the currency exchange rate has no bearing on relative prices, it
is not a factor in determining the
pattern of trade in the barter exchange model.
3
3 A Simple Model of Trade with Fixed Initial Endowments
The basis for barter trade is the difference in autarkic relative
prices. What causes the autarkic
relative prices to be different between countries? Some of the
factors that come to mind are differ-
ent tastes, different endowments, and different costs of
production. Identical tastes with different
endowments among traders can cause trade. Similarly, identical
endowments with different tastes
can also cause trade. In this section, we study a simple pure
exchange economy that allows for
different tastes and different fixed endowments. There are no
production activities in this model.
Goods are already produced and are in fixed supply. LetSj
andDj be the supply and demand
(consumption) of Gj in H, andS�j andD
�
j be their counterparts in F(j = 1;2). Assume H exports
G1 and imports G2. LetX andM be the exports and imports of H
andX� andM� be the foreign
counterparts:
X � S1 �D1; M � D2 �S2
X� � S�2 �D
�
2; M
� � D�1 �S
�
1 (2)
H’s national expenditure under autarky isp1D1 +p2D2, and its
GDP isp1S1 +p2S2, which is also
its national income. By the national income identity,p1D1 +
p2D2 = p1S1 + p2S2: Under free
trade, domestic prices are equal to foreign prices (assuming that
the same currency units are used
or that the units of currencies are redefined so that the exchange
rate is one). The home country’s
budget constraint is
p1D1 +p2D2 = p1S1 +p2S2; (3)
which shows that a country’s national expenditure is equal to its
national income.2 Rearranging
terms, we havep1 (S1 �D1) = p2 (D2 �S2) ; which yields the
following balance-of-trade equi-
librium condition under free trade (pj = p
�
j):
p�1X = p
�
2M , p
�X = M: (4)
2Note that the prices and the demand and supply configurations
will be different between autarky and free trade
in both countries. For ease of notation, we continue using the
same notations in both situations.
4
This condition shows that the home country’s total value of
exports is equal to the total value of
imports, evaluated at world prices.
Analogously, F’s budget constraint is
p�1D
�
1 +p
�
2D
�
2 = p
�
1S
�
1 +p
�
2S
�
2; (5)
which implies
p�1M
� = p�2X
� , p�M� = X�: (6)
Equilibrium in the world markets requires that total world
demand be equal to total world
supply for each good:
D1 +D
�
1 = S1 +S
�
1; (7)
D2 +D
�
2 = S2 +S
�
2; (8)
which are equivalent to
X = M�; (9)
X� = M: (10)
The two market-clearing conditions in (7) and (8) are not
independent. By summing the two
countries’ budget constraints in (3) and (5) and noting that
under free trade,pj = p
�
j; we obtain
p�1 (D1 +D
�
1 �S1 �S
�
1)+p
�
2 (D2 +D
�
2 �S2 �S
�
2) = 0: (11)
Given thatp�1 > 0 andp
�
2 > 0; if one market is in equilibrium (either (7) or (8) holds),
the other
market must also be in equilibrium. This isWalras’ Law . In
mathematical terms, the two market-
clearing conditions are not independent of each other. Eq. (11)
can be alternatively expressed
5
as
p�1 (M
� �X)+p�2 (M �X
�) = 0: (12)
M� �X is the world excess demand for G1 andM �X� the
world excess demand for G2. Thus,
Walras’ Law says thatthe sum of the values of world excess
demands in both markets is zero.
It follows thatM� = X if and only if M = X�:
Walras’ Law as expressed in (11) can be readily generalized to
then-good case. Let the world
excess demand for Gj beEj �
�
Dj +D
�
j
�
�
�
Sj +S
�
j
�
: Then, Walras’ Law in then-good case is
nX
j=1
p�jEj = 0: (13)
This indicates thatthe sum of the values of world excess
demands over all markets must be zero.If
anyn�1 markets are in equilibrium, the remaining one must also
be in equilibrium.
3.1 The Gains from Trade in a Pure Exchange World Economy
To analyze the existence of gains from trade, consider the
simple two-country, two-good model
with fixed endowments. PointE in Fig. 1 is H’s endowment
point with(S1;S2) measured from
the origin0. It is also F’s endowment point with(S�1;S
�
2) measured from the origin0
�. The size
of the box is determined by the fixed world supplies of both
goods. The horizontal axis measures
the demands for G1 in both countries, and the vertical axis
measures demand for G2. Assume that
each country has an aggregate utility function that only depends
on the bundle of consumption.
The autarkic utility levels are illustrated by the indifference
curvesU0 = U (D1;D2) = U (S1;S2)
andU�0 = U
� (D�1;D
�
2) = U
� (S�1;S
�
2) for H and F, respectively. For H, the consumption set
bounded below by theU0 curve is preferred to autarky, and for
F, the consumption set bounded
below by theU�0 curve in reference to its origin is also
preferred to autarky. Thus, the mutually
compatible preferred region is in the lensEABA�. If the two
countries can exchange goods so
that the final consumption point lies in the lens, then both are
better off with trade. This lens is
called the bargaining set. For H, the highestU achievable
subject to the bargaining set is pointA;
6
and for F, it isA�. The line0A�A0� is the locus of the tangent
points of the two indifference maps.
This locus is calledthe contract curve (and also called the
conflict curve). It has the property that
any move from a point on the contract curve will necessarily
lower at least one party’s utility. The
contract curve is the set of Pareto efficient allocations. A point
off the contract curve such asG
in Fig. 1 is not Pareto efficient since a new allocation away
fromG toward the contract curve can
improve at least one party’s utility without having to reduce the
other’s. It follows that an efficient
outcome with the initial bargaining point atE must settle at a
point in the segmentAA� of the
contract curve. This segment is calledthe "core" of the
economy. If the reallocation is achieved
through the bargaining process in the two party world, the final
outcome is in the core. The exact
outcome depends on relative bargaining skills and other factors
in the bargaining process.
Figure 1:
The box diagram in a simple exchange model
*
2S2S
*A
*0
*
0U
*
1U
1U
0U
B
A
G
0
1S 1
D
E
2D *1S*
1D
C
*
2D
Consider now the case in which each country has many traders
and therefore the economy
is a competitive one—each trader is a price taker and the market
prices are influenced by the
market excess demand or supply of the goods. A representative
trader facing market prices tries
to maximize their utility subject to the budget constraint. If all
traders in a country are identical,
7
then the home country’s traders will chooseD1 andD2 to
maximizeU (D1;D2) subject to (3), or
equivalently
pD1 +D2 = pS1 +S2: (14)
Each solvedDj is a function ofp andpS1 + S2, which is the
national income in terms of G2.
3
With S1 andS2 fixed in the present model, the national income
is also a function ofp, which is the
terms of trade. Thus,Dj = Dj (p) : Similarly, for F,D
�
j = D
�
j (p
�) :
Under free trade,p = p�: The equilibriump� is determined by
the market clearing conditions.4
As already discussed, Walras’ Law implies that only one of the
market equilibrium conditions in
(7) and (8) is needed for this purpose. Take, for example, the
G1 market clearing condition (7):
D1 (p)+D
�
1 (p
�) = S1 +S
�
1: (15)
This equation can be used to solve for the equilibrium terms of
tradep�(= p): Clearly, the equilib-
rium p� is determined byS1 + S
�
1 and the underlying preferences of both countries. Fig. 2 is the
graphical representation of (15).
Alternatively, one can use the export and import functions to
solve for the equilibriump�: From
(15), we can rewrite (9) asX (p) = M� (p�) ; which can be
solved for the same solution set. Fig. 3
shows this alternative way of determining the equilibrium terms
of trade.
3To solve this problem, set up the Lagrangian
functionL(D1;D2;�) = U (D1;D2) +
�(pS1 +S2 �pD1 �D2) ; where � is the Lagrange multiplier.
By embedding the constraint into the La-
grangian function and introducing the new variable�, the
original constrained maximization problem is equivalent
to maximizing the unconstrainedL function with respect to the
three variables,D1; D2 and �: The first-order
conditions are:@[email protected] = U1 � �p = 0;
@[email protected] = U2 � � = 0
[email protected][email protected]� = pS1 + S2 � pD1 � D2 =
0;
whereUj � @[email protected]: These three conditions are used
to solve for the three variables. Note that from the first two
conditions, we haveU1=U2 = p; namely, the marginal utility
ratio is the price ratio at the optimum. Let the utility
attained at the optimum be�U: From the indifference curveU
(D1;D2) = �U; we haveU1dD1 + U2dD2 = 0; which
implies that the marginal rate of substitution
(MRS)�dD2=dD1jU=�U is equal toU1=U2; and hence is equal
top:
4In the pure exchange model with no specification of the money
markets, the nominal money prices(p�1;p
�
2) are
indeterminate. This is seen by noting that if(p�1;p
�
2) is a solution, then(�p
�
1;�p
�
2) is also a solution for any� > 0:
By changing all money prices by the same proportion, the
budget constraints are unaffected, and the money income is
also changed by the same proportion. Thus, the chosen demands
will remain unchanged and the chosen trade volumes
will also be unchanged; here only the relative price matters.
8
Figure 2:
The determination of the equilibrium terms of trade
p=p*
*
1 1S S+
( ) ( )*1 1 *p DD p+
0
* *
1 1 1 1, SD D S+ +
p, p*
3.2 The Offer Curves
Consider Fig. 4, in whichE is the endowment point of the home
country. The budget constraint
in (3) are lines that go through pointE under different prices.
Ifp� = a; the highest utility
attainable under the budget lineEK is Ua with the preferred
consumption point atK: Similarly,
at p� = b; the preferred consumption point isN: The collection
of all the preferred consumption
points for different values ofp� is the curveEKN: This curve,
viewed from the origin0; is a price
consumption curve; if viewed from the new originE; it is the
offer curve. Atp� = a; H will offer
EY of G1 for YK of G2. At p� = b; H will offer EZ of G1 for
ZN of G2. The offer curve thus
portrays the utility-maximizing bundle of desired trade for
various values ofp�: If the price line is
sufficiently flat (the relative price of G1 is sufficiently low),
the desired trading point moves to the
south-east region ofE: In this case, the trade pattern is
reversed—H will want to export G2 and
import G1. Depending upon the indifference map, the offer
curve can have quite different shapes.
9
Figure 3:
p=p*
( )X p
( )* *M p
0
*,X M
p, p*
Fig. 5 plots the offer curve in the(X;M) axes. It is the mirror-
image of Fig. 4 withE as the new
origin. This curve shows thereciprocal demands schedule, which
demonstrates that a nation’s
exports are for the purpose of obtaining imports. There are no
free meals on earth. As the terms
of tradep� moves froma to b; the optimal trading point moves
fromK to N: LinesEa andEb are
generated by the balance-of-trade equilibrium condition given
in (4). An increase inp�, which is
the same as an increase inM=X, gives the home country
improved terms of trade, in which a unit
of exports can be exchanged for more units of imports.
3.3 Determination and Stability of a Trading Equilibrium
The foreign country’s offer curve is the mirror image of the
home’s, with the horizontal axisM�(in
G1) and the vertical axisX� (in G2). By superimposing the
home and foreign offer curves in one
graph, we obtain Fig. 6.
Equilibrium occurs at the intersection pointT of the two offer
curves0O and 0O�: At T;
X = M�, andM = X�, both markets are cleared. Desired exports
of one country are matched by
10
Figure 4:
Derivation of the offer curve
the desired imports of the other. Trade can therefore take place
at theequilibrium terms of trade
p�: Clearly, at the trading pointT; both countries’ balances of
trade are in equilibrium:p�X =
M = X� = p�M�:
The attainment of the equilibriump� in a competitive economy
should be addressed further.
Suppose that temporarily the price line is0a as shown in Fig. 6.
H’s chosen trading point isK and
F’s isJ: In this case, we haveM� > X andM < X�: G1 has
excess demand in the world market
and G2 excess supply. It is reasonable to hypothesize that if a
good is in excess demand, its price
will rise, and if in excess supply, its price will fall. If trade can
only take place given a contract that
matches the desired trading volumes of both traders, then at the
price line0a, the desired trading
volumes wouldn’t match, and therefore, the competitive market
force will push upp�1 and push
downp�2: Thus, the price ratiop
� (� p�1=p�2) will go up. This process will continue as long
as the
11
Figure 5:
The offer curve
ZY
N
X
M
E
a
K
O
b
markets are not cleared. Eventually, the equilibrium price
line0T is reached, and the equilibrium
terms of tradep�are established.
From the offer curve analysis, one can easily verify Walras’
Law. At the price line0a; the price
ratio isp�a1 =p
�a
2 : G1 has a world excess demand in the amount ofM
��X, and G2 has a world excess
supply ofX� �M: The slope of the0a line isp�a1 =p�a2 ,
which is equal to(X� �M)=(M� �X) :
Thus,p�a1 (M
� �X) = p�a2 (X� �M) ; or equivalently,p�a1 (M� �X) +
p�a2 (M �X�) = 0; is
Walras’ Law as already shown in (12).
3.4 The Possibility of Multiple Equilibria
As previously mentioned, since the shape of an offer curve
depends on the indifference map and
the initial endowments, it can exhibit strange shapes. Fig. 7
illustrates a case of multiple equilibria.
12
Figure 6:
Trading equilibrium
J
V
W
a
ZY
T
X, M*
M, X*
0
K
O
p*
O*
It has three equilibrium terms of trade. It can be verified that if
the price line is in the conep�0p�00
or below it, the price ratio will converge towardp�0. But if it is
in the conep�00p�000 or above it,
the price ratio will converge towardp�000. Thus,p�0 andp�000
are stable butp�00 is unstable. A slight
disturbance of the price away fromp�00 will accelerate the
price divergence toward eitherp�0 or p�000:
4 Example: Price Formation in P.O.W. Camps
R. A. Radford was an Allied prisoner of war in Italian and
German prison camps during WWII. In
Radford(1945), he documents how markets developed among
prisoners based on the allocations
of Red Cross parcels, which were quite regularly and evenly
distributed among prisoners. For
example, a nonsmoker would find it beneficial to trade his
cigarettes for canned foods from smok-
ers. This was an economy with no production, but exchanges
still took place. Different national
13
Figure 7:
Multiple equilibria
* 'p
* '''p
O*
O
'''T
'T
''T
X, M*
M, X*
0
* ''p
groups in different camps showed different relative prices—
coffee was relatively more expensive
in French camps and tea in English ones. Cigarettes evolved as
a medium of exchange. A trader
starting with a fixed bundle of goods gained by trading
(arbitraging) through different camps.
Eventually, equilibrium market prices quoted in terms of
cigarettes were observed across camps.
Since the medium of exchange itself was a consumable
commodity, the phenomena of inflation
and deflation due to currency creation and destruction were
observed during a rationing cycle. To
reap better terms of trade, some nonsmokers would wait until a
later stage of the rationing cycle
to sell his cigarettes when cigarettes became relatively scarce.
Coffee shops and laundry services
were established by the prisoners in the camps, turning a pure
exchange economy into one with
production!
14
5 The Optimality of a Competitive Trading World
In a competitive world economy, each country’s traders observe
given world prices while trying
to maximize their utilities subject to their budget constraints.
By assuming the existence of a
social utility function, we have derived the offer curves for both
countries. The optimality of the
competitive economy can be further illuminated by adding the
offer curves in the box diagram,
as shown in Fig. 8. PointT is the trading point as it is the
intersection of the two offer curves
EO andEO�: SinceT is on H’s offer curve, there is a home
country’s indifference curveUT
that is tangent to the price linep (= p�) : Similarly, there is a
foreign country’s indifference curve
U�T that is also tangent to thep
� line. By trading to pointT from the endowment pointE; the
home country’s utility level increases fromU0 to UT; and the
foreign country’s increases from
U�0 to U
�
T : Both countries move to a higher indifference curve. The
gains from trade are clearly
revealed. Moreover, since pointT is the tangent point ofUT
andU
�
T ; it must be on the contract
curve. Thus, free trade is Pareto efficient. In addition, a free
trade equilibrium must be in the core
of the economy. In the case of market power, as discussed
earlier in the bargaining case, the core
is represented by the line segmentAA�: Economic theory on the
core shows that as the number
of agents in the market increases, the core shrinks in size and
approximates the set of competitive
equilibria. Thus, a competitive economy is Pareto efficient.
6 Appendix
6.1 The Marshall-Lerner Condition
The condition for the stability of an equilibrium is related to
how excess demands adjust when
there is a change in the price ratio. The adjustment can be
expressed in terms of the price elasticity
of import demand. Let the home and foreign country’s price
elasticities of import demand be
respectively defined as
" � �
�
1
p
�
dM
Md
�
1
p
�; "� � �p�dM�
M�dp�
: (16)
15
Figure 8:
Free trade is Pareto efficient
*
2S2S
*A
*0
*
0U
*
1U
1U
0U
B A
TU
0
1S
1D
E
2D *1S*
1D
T
*
2D
*
TU
*p p=
*O
O
Note thatM is in G2, and its relative price (in terms of G1)
is1=p (� p2=p1) in the home country.
Likewise, M� is in G1, and its relative price (in terms of G2)
isp� in the foreign country. The
negative sign attached to both definitions makes both
elasticities positive in the normal sense.
Recall that the world excess demand for G1 isE1 = M
� �X: Using the home country’s balance-
of-trade equilibrium condition (4), we have
E1 = M
� �M=p�: (17)
Under free trade,p = p�; and therefore,M is a function of1=p�,
or equivalently, a function of
p�. Thus,E1 is also a function ofp
� and can be expressed asE1 (p
�) : Stability arises if a small
16
increase inp� at the equilibrium point results in a decrease inE1
so thatE1 becomes negative
(or equivalently, a world excess supply is generated). This
ensures that the market force will pull
p� back to its initial equilibrium.5 This is equivalent to
requiring that theE1 (p
�) function be
negatively sloped in the neighborhood of the equilibrium point:
E01 (p
�) < 0: (18)
Thus, from (17), we obtain
dM�
dp�
�
p�dM=dp� �M
(p�)
2
< 0;
which implies
�
p�dM�
M�dp�
+
dM
M�dp�
>
M
p�M�
: (19)
At the equilibrium point,E1 = 0 and, therefore,M
� = M=p�: Thus,
dM
M�dp�
=
p�dM
Mdp�
= �
�
1
p�
�
dM
Md
�
1
p�
� = �
�
1
p
�
dM
Md
�
1
p
� = " and M
p�M�
= 1: (20)
Using (19) and (20), the local stability condition (18) is
equivalent to
"+"� > 1: (21)
This is the Marshall-Lerner condition —the sum of the price
elasticities of both countries’ de-
mands for imports must be greater than one for the trading
system to be locally stable.
The Marshall-Lerner condition appears in a number of trade
models. Applying it to the de-
valuation model, the Marshall-Lerner condition ensures that a
devaluation of a nation’s currency
improves its balance of trade.
5The adjustment process can be hypothesized as_p� = kE1 (p
�) ; wherek is the speed of adjustment. For this
differential equation to have a stable solution, it is required that
its characteristic root have a negative real part.
17
6.2 Graphical Representation of the Price Elasticity of Import
Demand
The price elasticity of import demand is a very important
variable in the theory and policy of trade.
It can be measured nicely by the use of the offer curve.
Consider the home offer curve shown in
Fig. 9. Under free trade,p� = p: At p; the desired trading point
isT; the desiredM is TN and the
desiredX is 0N: Draw a tangent line atT to the offer curve0O
with the intercept on the horizontal
axis at pointI. Recall that" � �(
1
p)dM
Md(1p)
= pdM
Mdp
: Using the home balance-of-trade equilibrium
condition (4), we havedp = dp� = d(M=X) = (XdM �MdX)=X2:
It follows that
" =
dM
Xdp
=
XdM
(XdM �MdX)
=
X
X �M dX
dM
: (22)
At point T; the slope of the offer curve isdM=dX = TN=IN:
Thus,dX=dM = IN=TN: Using
0N � IN = 0I; we obtain
" =
0N
0I
: (23)
At T; the import demand is elastic since" > 1: If point T is at a
point on the offer curve that
has a vertical tangent line, then" = 1: If the offer curve bends
back such that the tangent line is
negatively sloped, then" < 1:
6.3 The Price Elasticity of the Supply of Exports
Imports and exports are related by the offer curve. Their
respective price elasticities are naturally
linked to each other. To obtain their precise relationship, lete
ande� be the home and foreign
countries’ price elasticities of the supply of exports,
respectively:
e �
pdX
Xdp
; e� �
�
1
p�
�
dX�
X�d
�
1
p�
�: (24)
18
Figure 9:
" = 0N=0I
I N
X
M
0
p
T
O
Under free trade,p = p�: Thus, the balance-of-trade equilibrium
condition (4) can be written as
pX = M. It follows thatX +pdX=dp = X +eX = dM=dp = "X by
(22), which implies
e = "�1: (25)
Similarly, we have
e� = "� �1: (26)
A country’s export supply elasticity is its import demand
elasticity minus one.
19
7 Reference
Radford, R. A. (1945), "The Economic Organization of a
P.O.W. Camp,"Economica12, 189-201.
8 Exercises
1. Using the numerical example given in (1), try to sell G2 from
H to F and sell G1 from F to
H. Are these trades profitable?
2. Let H be the U.S. and F be the U.K. and let the U.S. foreign
exchange rate bee dollars per
pound sterling.
(a) Assume that initiallye = 1 ($1 = $1) : If the autarkic price
matrix is
2
64 p1 p�1
p2 p
�
2
3
75 =
2
64 6 8
1 2
3
75 ; what are the autarkic prices in the U.K. expressed in terms
of dollars? Can
the U.K. export any good?
(b) If the pound is devalued and the newe = 0:1 ($1 = $0:1); can
the U.S. export any
good?
(c) What pattern of trade do you obtain in (a) and (b) above?
(d) Is the pattern of trade affected by the value ofe in the barter
exchange model?
3. If inflation is across the board in a country affecting every
good’s price by the same propor-
tion, will it affect the pattern of trade in the barter exchange
model?
4. Fig. 3 uses the G1 market clearing condition (9) to find the
equilibriump�: Plot a similar
figure using the G2 market clearing condition in (10). Pay
special attention to the labeling
of the price axis.
5. In Fig. 6, if a disequilibrium price ratio, say0b; is above the
pointT; which good has a world
excess demand and which has a world excess supply? Deduce
the direction of movements
20
of the disequilibrium price ratiop�b1 =p
�b
2 .
6. Prove that in Fig. 7,p�0 andp�000 are stable butp�00 is
unstable.
7. In a pure exchange economy, there are two goods, 1 and 2,
and two countries, Home and
Foreign, having the endowment vectors(S1;S2) = (10;0) and(S
�
1;S
�
2) = (0;10) and the
utility functionsU = D
1
4
1 D
3
4
2 andU
� = D�1D
�
2; respectively.
(a) Derive both goods’ world excess demand functions.
(b) Show that both world excess demand functions are functions
of only the relative prices
p = p1=p2 or 1=p = p2=p1:
(c) Solve the equilibrium terms of tradep:
(d) Prove the Walras law in this model.
8. " is defined as�(
1
p)dM
Md(1p)
: Prove that" is also equal topdM
Mdp
:
9. Assume free trade and the two countries’ import functions
areM = 2
�
1
p
��0:4
andM� =
3(p�)
�0:8
: Is this trading system stable? Why? (Hint: check to see if the
Marshall-Lerner
condition is satisfied.)
10. Assume that the home country’s offer curve isM = f (X) =
5X2: If the equilibrium terms
of trade arep� = 10; what are the equilibriumX andM? (Hint:
use the balance of trade
equilibrium conditionp�X = M.)
21
IntroductionThe Determinants of Barter TradesA Simple Model
of Trade with Fixed Initial EndowmentsThe Gains from Trade
in a Pure Exchange World EconomyThe Offer
CurvesDetermination and Stability of a Trading EquilibriumThe
Possibility of Multiple EquilibriaExample: Price Formation in
P.O.W. CampsThe Optimality of a Competitive Trading
WorldAppendixThe Marshall-Lerner ConditionGraphical
Representation of the Price Elasticity of Import DemandThe
Price Elasticity of the Supply of ExportsReferenceExercises

More Related Content

Similar to Department of Economics, University at Buffalo Winston Chang.docx

11 foreign-exchange
11 foreign-exchange11 foreign-exchange
11 foreign-exchange
domsr
 
Foreign exchange
Foreign exchangeForeign exchange
Foreign exchange
domsr
 
Chapter 10- Foreign Exchange Market-2020-2021.ppt
Chapter 10- Foreign Exchange Market-2020-2021.pptChapter 10- Foreign Exchange Market-2020-2021.ppt
Chapter 10- Foreign Exchange Market-2020-2021.ppt
ShahinshaHcu1
 
Exchange rate & international trade
Exchange rate & international tradeExchange rate & international trade
Exchange rate & international trade
ElhadiTabar
 
International finance
International financeInternational finance
International finance
nileshsen
 
UV4252 Rev. Aug. 13, 2015 This technical note was p.docx
UV4252 Rev. Aug. 13, 2015  This technical note was p.docxUV4252 Rev. Aug. 13, 2015  This technical note was p.docx
UV4252 Rev. Aug. 13, 2015 This technical note was p.docx
dickonsondorris
 

Similar to Department of Economics, University at Buffalo Winston Chang.docx (20)

11 foreign-exchange
11 foreign-exchange11 foreign-exchange
11 foreign-exchange
 
Foreign exchange
Foreign exchangeForeign exchange
Foreign exchange
 
Basics of open market Economies
Basics of open market EconomiesBasics of open market Economies
Basics of open market Economies
 
Forex ch. 9
Forex ch. 9Forex ch. 9
Forex ch. 9
 
Forex
Forex Forex
Forex
 
31
3131
31
 
Fiancial Econometrics Paper - Final Draft
Fiancial Econometrics Paper - Final DraftFiancial Econometrics Paper - Final Draft
Fiancial Econometrics Paper - Final Draft
 
Forex
ForexForex
Forex
 
Chapter 10- Foreign Exchange Market-2020-2021.ppt
Chapter 10- Foreign Exchange Market-2020-2021.pptChapter 10- Foreign Exchange Market-2020-2021.ppt
Chapter 10- Foreign Exchange Market-2020-2021.ppt
 
Brotherhood of competition: foreign direct investment and domestic mergers
Brotherhood of competition: foreign direct investment and domestic mergersBrotherhood of competition: foreign direct investment and domestic mergers
Brotherhood of competition: foreign direct investment and domestic mergers
 
Exchange rate & international trade
Exchange rate & international tradeExchange rate & international trade
Exchange rate & international trade
 
Factor endowments and the heckscher ohlin theory (chapter 5)
Factor endowments and the heckscher ohlin theory (chapter 5)Factor endowments and the heckscher ohlin theory (chapter 5)
Factor endowments and the heckscher ohlin theory (chapter 5)
 
Ppp.f00
Ppp.f00Ppp.f00
Ppp.f00
 
Offer curves
Offer curvesOffer curves
Offer curves
 
International finance
International financeInternational finance
International finance
 
Exchange rate final
Exchange rate finalExchange rate final
Exchange rate final
 
International Economics
International EconomicsInternational Economics
International Economics
 
Hecsher-ohlin theorem, Modern theory of international trade.
Hecsher-ohlin theorem, Modern theory of international trade.Hecsher-ohlin theorem, Modern theory of international trade.
Hecsher-ohlin theorem, Modern theory of international trade.
 
UV4252 Rev. Aug. 13, 2015 This technical note was p.docx
UV4252 Rev. Aug. 13, 2015  This technical note was p.docxUV4252 Rev. Aug. 13, 2015  This technical note was p.docx
UV4252 Rev. Aug. 13, 2015 This technical note was p.docx
 
19 the open economy
19 the open economy19 the open economy
19 the open economy
 

More from simonithomas47935

HOSP3075 Brand Analysis Paper 1This is the first of three assignme.docx
HOSP3075 Brand Analysis Paper 1This is the first of three assignme.docxHOSP3075 Brand Analysis Paper 1This is the first of three assignme.docx
HOSP3075 Brand Analysis Paper 1This is the first of three assignme.docx
simonithomas47935
 
Hou, J., Li, Y., Yu, J. & Shi, W. (2020). A Survey on Digital Fo.docx
Hou, J., Li, Y., Yu, J. & Shi, W. (2020). A Survey on Digital Fo.docxHou, J., Li, Y., Yu, J. & Shi, W. (2020). A Survey on Digital Fo.docx
Hou, J., Li, Y., Yu, J. & Shi, W. (2020). A Survey on Digital Fo.docx
simonithomas47935
 
How (Not) to be Secular by James K.A. SmithSecular (1)—the ea.docx
How (Not) to be Secular by James K.A. SmithSecular (1)—the ea.docxHow (Not) to be Secular by James K.A. SmithSecular (1)—the ea.docx
How (Not) to be Secular by James K.A. SmithSecular (1)—the ea.docx
simonithomas47935
 
hoose (1) one childhood experience from the list provided below..docx
hoose (1) one childhood experience from the list provided below..docxhoose (1) one childhood experience from the list provided below..docx
hoose (1) one childhood experience from the list provided below..docx
simonithomas47935
 
HomeAnnouncementsSyllabusDiscussionsQuizzesGra.docx
HomeAnnouncementsSyllabusDiscussionsQuizzesGra.docxHomeAnnouncementsSyllabusDiscussionsQuizzesGra.docx
HomeAnnouncementsSyllabusDiscussionsQuizzesGra.docx
simonithomas47935
 

More from simonithomas47935 (20)

Hours, A. (2014). Reading Fairy Tales and Playing A Way of Treati.docx
Hours, A. (2014). Reading Fairy Tales and Playing A Way of Treati.docxHours, A. (2014). Reading Fairy Tales and Playing A Way of Treati.docx
Hours, A. (2014). Reading Fairy Tales and Playing A Way of Treati.docx
 
How are authentication and authorization alike and how are the.docx
How are authentication and authorization alike and how are the.docxHow are authentication and authorization alike and how are the.docx
How are authentication and authorization alike and how are the.docx
 
How are self-esteem and self-concept different What is the or.docx
How are self-esteem and self-concept different What is the or.docxHow are self-esteem and self-concept different What is the or.docx
How are self-esteem and self-concept different What is the or.docx
 
How are morality and religion similar and how are they different.docx
How are morality and religion similar and how are they different.docxHow are morality and religion similar and how are they different.docx
How are morality and religion similar and how are they different.docx
 
How are financial statements used to evaluate business activities.docx
How are financial statements used to evaluate business activities.docxHow are financial statements used to evaluate business activities.docx
How are financial statements used to evaluate business activities.docx
 
How are Japanese and Chinese Americans similar How are they differe.docx
How are Japanese and Chinese Americans similar How are they differe.docxHow are Japanese and Chinese Americans similar How are they differe.docx
How are Japanese and Chinese Americans similar How are they differe.docx
 
Hot Spot PolicingPlace can be an important aspect of crime and.docx
Hot Spot PolicingPlace can be an important aspect of crime and.docxHot Spot PolicingPlace can be an important aspect of crime and.docx
Hot Spot PolicingPlace can be an important aspect of crime and.docx
 
HOSP3075 Brand Analysis Paper 1This is the first of three assignme.docx
HOSP3075 Brand Analysis Paper 1This is the first of three assignme.docxHOSP3075 Brand Analysis Paper 1This is the first of three assignme.docx
HOSP3075 Brand Analysis Paper 1This is the first of three assignme.docx
 
Hou, J., Li, Y., Yu, J. & Shi, W. (2020). A Survey on Digital Fo.docx
Hou, J., Li, Y., Yu, J. & Shi, W. (2020). A Survey on Digital Fo.docxHou, J., Li, Y., Yu, J. & Shi, W. (2020). A Survey on Digital Fo.docx
Hou, J., Li, Y., Yu, J. & Shi, W. (2020). A Survey on Digital Fo.docx
 
How (Not) to be Secular by James K.A. SmithSecular (1)—the ea.docx
How (Not) to be Secular by James K.A. SmithSecular (1)—the ea.docxHow (Not) to be Secular by James K.A. SmithSecular (1)—the ea.docx
How (Not) to be Secular by James K.A. SmithSecular (1)—the ea.docx
 
Hopefully, you enjoyed this class on Digital Media and Society.Q.docx
Hopefully, you enjoyed this class on Digital Media and Society.Q.docxHopefully, you enjoyed this class on Digital Media and Society.Q.docx
Hopefully, you enjoyed this class on Digital Media and Society.Q.docx
 
hoose (1) one childhood experience from the list provided below..docx
hoose (1) one childhood experience from the list provided below..docxhoose (1) one childhood experience from the list provided below..docx
hoose (1) one childhood experience from the list provided below..docx
 
honesty, hard work, caring, excellence HIS 1110 Dr. .docx
honesty, hard work, caring, excellence  HIS 1110      Dr. .docxhonesty, hard work, caring, excellence  HIS 1110      Dr. .docx
honesty, hard work, caring, excellence HIS 1110 Dr. .docx
 
hoose one of the four following visualsImage courtesy o.docx
hoose one of the four following visualsImage courtesy o.docxhoose one of the four following visualsImage courtesy o.docx
hoose one of the four following visualsImage courtesy o.docx
 
HomeworkChoose a site used by the public such as a supermark.docx
HomeworkChoose a site used by the public such as a supermark.docxHomeworkChoose a site used by the public such as a supermark.docx
HomeworkChoose a site used by the public such as a supermark.docx
 
Homework 2 Please answer the following questions in small paragraph.docx
Homework 2 Please answer the following questions in small paragraph.docxHomework 2 Please answer the following questions in small paragraph.docx
Homework 2 Please answer the following questions in small paragraph.docx
 
HomeNotificationsMy CommunityBBA 2010-16J-5A21-S1, Introductio.docx
HomeNotificationsMy CommunityBBA 2010-16J-5A21-S1, Introductio.docxHomeNotificationsMy CommunityBBA 2010-16J-5A21-S1, Introductio.docx
HomeNotificationsMy CommunityBBA 2010-16J-5A21-S1, Introductio.docx
 
HomeAnnouncementsSyllabusDiscussionsQuizzesGra.docx
HomeAnnouncementsSyllabusDiscussionsQuizzesGra.docxHomeAnnouncementsSyllabusDiscussionsQuizzesGra.docx
HomeAnnouncementsSyllabusDiscussionsQuizzesGra.docx
 
Homeless The Motel Kids of Orange CountyWrite a 1-2 page pa.docx
Homeless The Motel Kids of Orange CountyWrite a 1-2 page pa.docxHomeless The Motel Kids of Orange CountyWrite a 1-2 page pa.docx
Homeless The Motel Kids of Orange CountyWrite a 1-2 page pa.docx
 
Home work 8 Date 042220201. what are the different between.docx
Home work  8 Date 042220201. what are the  different between.docxHome work  8 Date 042220201. what are the  different between.docx
Home work 8 Date 042220201. what are the different between.docx
 

Recently uploaded

Making and Justifying Mathematical Decisions.pdf
Making and Justifying Mathematical Decisions.pdfMaking and Justifying Mathematical Decisions.pdf
Making and Justifying Mathematical Decisions.pdf
Chris Hunter
 
Activity 01 - Artificial Culture (1).pdf
Activity 01 - Artificial Culture (1).pdfActivity 01 - Artificial Culture (1).pdf
Activity 01 - Artificial Culture (1).pdf
ciinovamais
 
The basics of sentences session 2pptx copy.pptx
The basics of sentences session 2pptx copy.pptxThe basics of sentences session 2pptx copy.pptx
The basics of sentences session 2pptx copy.pptx
heathfieldcps1
 

Recently uploaded (20)

Role Of Transgenic Animal In Target Validation-1.pptx
Role Of Transgenic Animal In Target Validation-1.pptxRole Of Transgenic Animal In Target Validation-1.pptx
Role Of Transgenic Animal In Target Validation-1.pptx
 
On National Teacher Day, meet the 2024-25 Kenan Fellows
On National Teacher Day, meet the 2024-25 Kenan FellowsOn National Teacher Day, meet the 2024-25 Kenan Fellows
On National Teacher Day, meet the 2024-25 Kenan Fellows
 
Making and Justifying Mathematical Decisions.pdf
Making and Justifying Mathematical Decisions.pdfMaking and Justifying Mathematical Decisions.pdf
Making and Justifying Mathematical Decisions.pdf
 
Z Score,T Score, Percential Rank and Box Plot Graph
Z Score,T Score, Percential Rank and Box Plot GraphZ Score,T Score, Percential Rank and Box Plot Graph
Z Score,T Score, Percential Rank and Box Plot Graph
 
TỔNG ÔN TẬP THI VÀO LỚP 10 MÔN TIẾNG ANH NĂM HỌC 2023 - 2024 CÓ ĐÁP ÁN (NGỮ Â...
TỔNG ÔN TẬP THI VÀO LỚP 10 MÔN TIẾNG ANH NĂM HỌC 2023 - 2024 CÓ ĐÁP ÁN (NGỮ Â...TỔNG ÔN TẬP THI VÀO LỚP 10 MÔN TIẾNG ANH NĂM HỌC 2023 - 2024 CÓ ĐÁP ÁN (NGỮ Â...
TỔNG ÔN TẬP THI VÀO LỚP 10 MÔN TIẾNG ANH NĂM HỌC 2023 - 2024 CÓ ĐÁP ÁN (NGỮ Â...
 
Micro-Scholarship, What it is, How can it help me.pdf
Micro-Scholarship, What it is, How can it help me.pdfMicro-Scholarship, What it is, How can it help me.pdf
Micro-Scholarship, What it is, How can it help me.pdf
 
Activity 01 - Artificial Culture (1).pdf
Activity 01 - Artificial Culture (1).pdfActivity 01 - Artificial Culture (1).pdf
Activity 01 - Artificial Culture (1).pdf
 
Sociology 101 Demonstration of Learning Exhibit
Sociology 101 Demonstration of Learning ExhibitSociology 101 Demonstration of Learning Exhibit
Sociology 101 Demonstration of Learning Exhibit
 
ICT Role in 21st Century Education & its Challenges.pptx
ICT Role in 21st Century Education & its Challenges.pptxICT Role in 21st Century Education & its Challenges.pptx
ICT Role in 21st Century Education & its Challenges.pptx
 
microwave assisted reaction. General introduction
microwave assisted reaction. General introductionmicrowave assisted reaction. General introduction
microwave assisted reaction. General introduction
 
Food Chain and Food Web (Ecosystem) EVS, B. Pharmacy 1st Year, Sem-II
Food Chain and Food Web (Ecosystem) EVS, B. Pharmacy 1st Year, Sem-IIFood Chain and Food Web (Ecosystem) EVS, B. Pharmacy 1st Year, Sem-II
Food Chain and Food Web (Ecosystem) EVS, B. Pharmacy 1st Year, Sem-II
 
How to Give a Domain for a Field in Odoo 17
How to Give a Domain for a Field in Odoo 17How to Give a Domain for a Field in Odoo 17
How to Give a Domain for a Field in Odoo 17
 
Key note speaker Neum_Admir Softic_ENG.pdf
Key note speaker Neum_Admir Softic_ENG.pdfKey note speaker Neum_Admir Softic_ENG.pdf
Key note speaker Neum_Admir Softic_ENG.pdf
 
The basics of sentences session 2pptx copy.pptx
The basics of sentences session 2pptx copy.pptxThe basics of sentences session 2pptx copy.pptx
The basics of sentences session 2pptx copy.pptx
 
Class 11th Physics NEET formula sheet pdf
Class 11th Physics NEET formula sheet pdfClass 11th Physics NEET formula sheet pdf
Class 11th Physics NEET formula sheet pdf
 
INDIA QUIZ 2024 RLAC DELHI UNIVERSITY.pptx
INDIA QUIZ 2024 RLAC DELHI UNIVERSITY.pptxINDIA QUIZ 2024 RLAC DELHI UNIVERSITY.pptx
INDIA QUIZ 2024 RLAC DELHI UNIVERSITY.pptx
 
Presentation by Andreas Schleicher Tackling the School Absenteeism Crisis 30 ...
Presentation by Andreas Schleicher Tackling the School Absenteeism Crisis 30 ...Presentation by Andreas Schleicher Tackling the School Absenteeism Crisis 30 ...
Presentation by Andreas Schleicher Tackling the School Absenteeism Crisis 30 ...
 
General Principles of Intellectual Property: Concepts of Intellectual Proper...
General Principles of Intellectual Property: Concepts of Intellectual  Proper...General Principles of Intellectual Property: Concepts of Intellectual  Proper...
General Principles of Intellectual Property: Concepts of Intellectual Proper...
 
Asian American Pacific Islander Month DDSD 2024.pptx
Asian American Pacific Islander Month DDSD 2024.pptxAsian American Pacific Islander Month DDSD 2024.pptx
Asian American Pacific Islander Month DDSD 2024.pptx
 
Advanced Views - Calendar View in Odoo 17
Advanced Views - Calendar View in Odoo 17Advanced Views - Calendar View in Odoo 17
Advanced Views - Calendar View in Odoo 17
 

Department of Economics, University at Buffalo Winston Chang.docx

  • 1. Department of Economics, University at Buffalo Winston Chang For use by students of my course only. Further distribution is prohibited.1 Simple Pure Exchange Models 1 Introduction The price of a good or service observed in a national market, without foreign trade, is determined by demand and supply in that nation. On the supply side, nations generally have different natural endowments, different factors of production, and different technologies relevant to the production of goods and services. These differences result in variations in production costs. On the demand side, people have different incomes and tastes, which generate unique patterns of demand among nations. Thus, the autarkic prices observed among nations tend to be different. Once foreign trade is opened up, goods and services move between nations. Some questions that come to mind when considering foreign trade are: Which country exports which good? What role do autarkic
  • 2. prices play in determining the direction of trade? What are the equilibrium terms of trade? Are there gains from trade? These are some of the basic questions to be answered in the study of international economics. In this chapter, we will consider some simple exchange models in order to illustrate the deter- minants of trade. It will be shown that it is the difference in relative autarkic prices, not money prices, that causes trade to take place. We will also examine the determination of the equilibrium terms of trade and gains from trade with the help of a simple exchange model, while keeping the supply of goods fixed. 2 The Determinants of Barter Trades To illustrate the basic determinants of trade, we consider a very simple pure exchange model in which there are two countries, called home (H) and foreign (F), and two goods, good 1 (G1) 1Copyright c 2009 by Winston Chang. All rights reserved. 1
  • 3. and good 2 (G2). Goods are already produced so there are no new production activities in either country. Before trade is opened up, each good has an autarkic price in each country. Let the home country’s variables be represented without an asterisk and foreign variables with an asterisk. Let pj be the money price of goodj in H (j = 1;2), measured, say, in U.S. dollars andp � j be the money price of goodj in F (j = 1;2), measured in British pounds. These are the money (nominal) prices observed in the autarkic (no foreign trade) equilibrium. Assume that there are no impediments to trade; namely, there are no transport costs or other trading costs. The markets are competitive, and the buyers and sellers all face the same prices. How is the trade pattern determined? Is it determined by these nominal prices? To answer both questions, we first consider a barter exchange economy in which one good is directly exchanged for the other. Since there are no trading costs, if the barter exchange ratios
  • 4. between the two goods in the two countries are different, gainful arbitrage activities will take place and trade will occur. A barter exchange ratio is nothing but the nominalprice ratio . Let p = p1=p2 which is called "the relative price of G1 (in terms of G2)" in H. It measuresp units of G2 that are exchanged for one unit of G1. For example, ifp1 = 10 andp2 = 5; thenp = 2, which means one unit of G1 can be exchanged for two units of G2. Formally,p1=p2 has the dimension of� $10 1G1 � = � $5 1G2 � = 2G2/1G1. The $ element is canceled out in the ratiop1=p2: Similarly, the relative price of G2 (in terms of G1) in H is1=p = p2=p1: The foreign autarkic relative price of G1 in terms of G2 isp� = p�1=p � 2: The following proposition shows that the determinants of trade are not the nominal autarkic
  • 5. prices but the relative autarkic prices. Proposition 1 Barter trade between a pair of goods can gainfully take place if theautarkic rela- tive pricesbetween the pair of goods in the two countries are different. A country will export the good whose relative autarkic price is cheaper than the other’s, and both countries can gain from the trade. 2 Consider the following autarkic price matrix: 2 64 p1 p�1 p2 p � 2 3 75 = 2 64 1 40 2 10 3 75 : (1)
  • 6. From this matrix, we know that one unit of G1 in H can be exchanged for 0.5 units of G2 (p = 1=2 = 0:5); but in the foreign country, one unit of G1 can be exchanged for four units of G2 (p� = 40=10 = 4): So if a merchant ships one unit of G1 from H to F, he can exchange that unit for four units of G2 in F, compared with only 0.5 units of G2 in H. He will therefore have a gain of 3.5 units of G2. If this gain is more than enough to pay for the transportation and other transactions costs, he will gain from the trade and export G1. Now think of F. Under autarky, a unit of G2 can be exchanged forp�2=p � 1 � 1=p� = 10=40 = 0:25 units of G1: If a merchant ships one unit of G2 from F to H, he can exchange that unit for p2=p1 = 2=1 = 2 units of G1. He will gain 1.75 units of G1. Thus, F will export G2. Unequal relative prices create the opportunity for profitable arbitrage, and since both countries gain from this transaction, trade emerges voluntarily. The above example illustratesa fundamental principle: if, under autarky,p1=p2 < p
  • 7. � 1=p � 2; then H will export G1, and F will export G2. It is easy to verify that ifp1=p2 > p � 1=p � 2; then the opposite trade pattern occurs. Thus, wheneverp1=p2 6= p�1=p�2; trade will take place. Furthermore, both countries gain from trade. Note that the relative prices are independent of currency units used in each country. If H is the U.S., F is the U.K., and$1 = $1; then the U.K.’s autarkic money prices in terms of dollars are both higher than those in the U.S. If trade was thought to be determined by comparing the money prices, then the U.K. would not have been able to export any good. It is theautarkic relative prices that matter in the determination of the pattern of barter trade, not thenominal money prices. Since the currency exchange rate has no bearing on relative prices, it is not a factor in determining the
  • 8. pattern of trade in the barter exchange model. 3 3 A Simple Model of Trade with Fixed Initial Endowments The basis for barter trade is the difference in autarkic relative prices. What causes the autarkic relative prices to be different between countries? Some of the factors that come to mind are differ- ent tastes, different endowments, and different costs of production. Identical tastes with different endowments among traders can cause trade. Similarly, identical endowments with different tastes can also cause trade. In this section, we study a simple pure exchange economy that allows for different tastes and different fixed endowments. There are no production activities in this model. Goods are already produced and are in fixed supply. LetSj andDj be the supply and demand (consumption) of Gj in H, andS�j andD � j be their counterparts in F(j = 1;2). Assume H exports G1 and imports G2. LetX andM be the exports and imports of H andX� andM� be the foreign
  • 9. counterparts: X � S1 �D1; M � D2 �S2 X� � S�2 �D � 2; M � � D�1 �S � 1 (2) H’s national expenditure under autarky isp1D1 +p2D2, and its GDP isp1S1 +p2S2, which is also its national income. By the national income identity,p1D1 + p2D2 = p1S1 + p2S2: Under free trade, domestic prices are equal to foreign prices (assuming that the same currency units are used or that the units of currencies are redefined so that the exchange rate is one). The home country’s budget constraint is p1D1 +p2D2 = p1S1 +p2S2; (3) which shows that a country’s national expenditure is equal to its national income.2 Rearranging terms, we havep1 (S1 �D1) = p2 (D2 �S2) ; which yields the following balance-of-trade equi- librium condition under free trade (pj = p
  • 10. � j): p�1X = p � 2M , p �X = M: (4) 2Note that the prices and the demand and supply configurations will be different between autarky and free trade in both countries. For ease of notation, we continue using the same notations in both situations. 4 This condition shows that the home country’s total value of exports is equal to the total value of imports, evaluated at world prices. Analogously, F’s budget constraint is p�1D � 1 +p � 2D � 2 = p �
  • 11. 1S � 1 +p � 2S � 2; (5) which implies p�1M � = p�2X � , p�M� = X�: (6) Equilibrium in the world markets requires that total world demand be equal to total world supply for each good: D1 +D � 1 = S1 +S � 1; (7) D2 +D � 2 = S2 +S � 2; (8)
  • 12. which are equivalent to X = M�; (9) X� = M: (10) The two market-clearing conditions in (7) and (8) are not independent. By summing the two countries’ budget constraints in (3) and (5) and noting that under free trade,pj = p � j; we obtain p�1 (D1 +D � 1 �S1 �S � 1)+p � 2 (D2 +D � 2 �S2 �S � 2) = 0: (11) Given thatp�1 > 0 andp � 2 > 0; if one market is in equilibrium (either (7) or (8) holds), the other
  • 13. market must also be in equilibrium. This isWalras’ Law . In mathematical terms, the two market- clearing conditions are not independent of each other. Eq. (11) can be alternatively expressed 5 as p�1 (M � �X)+p�2 (M �X �) = 0: (12) M� �X is the world excess demand for G1 andM �X� the world excess demand for G2. Thus, Walras’ Law says thatthe sum of the values of world excess demands in both markets is zero. It follows thatM� = X if and only if M = X�: Walras’ Law as expressed in (11) can be readily generalized to then-good case. Let the world excess demand for Gj beEj � � Dj +D � j �
  • 14. � � Sj +S � j � : Then, Walras’ Law in then-good case is nX j=1 p�jEj = 0: (13) This indicates thatthe sum of the values of world excess demands over all markets must be zero.If anyn�1 markets are in equilibrium, the remaining one must also be in equilibrium. 3.1 The Gains from Trade in a Pure Exchange World Economy To analyze the existence of gains from trade, consider the simple two-country, two-good model with fixed endowments. PointE in Fig. 1 is H’s endowment point with(S1;S2) measured from the origin0. It is also F’s endowment point with(S�1;S � 2) measured from the origin0 �. The size of the box is determined by the fixed world supplies of both
  • 15. goods. The horizontal axis measures the demands for G1 in both countries, and the vertical axis measures demand for G2. Assume that each country has an aggregate utility function that only depends on the bundle of consumption. The autarkic utility levels are illustrated by the indifference curvesU0 = U (D1;D2) = U (S1;S2) andU�0 = U � (D�1;D � 2) = U � (S�1;S � 2) for H and F, respectively. For H, the consumption set bounded below by theU0 curve is preferred to autarky, and for F, the consumption set bounded below by theU�0 curve in reference to its origin is also preferred to autarky. Thus, the mutually compatible preferred region is in the lensEABA�. If the two countries can exchange goods so that the final consumption point lies in the lens, then both are better off with trade. This lens is called the bargaining set. For H, the highestU achievable subject to the bargaining set is pointA;
  • 16. 6 and for F, it isA�. The line0A�A0� is the locus of the tangent points of the two indifference maps. This locus is calledthe contract curve (and also called the conflict curve). It has the property that any move from a point on the contract curve will necessarily lower at least one party’s utility. The contract curve is the set of Pareto efficient allocations. A point off the contract curve such asG in Fig. 1 is not Pareto efficient since a new allocation away fromG toward the contract curve can improve at least one party’s utility without having to reduce the other’s. It follows that an efficient outcome with the initial bargaining point atE must settle at a point in the segmentAA� of the contract curve. This segment is calledthe "core" of the economy. If the reallocation is achieved through the bargaining process in the two party world, the final outcome is in the core. The exact outcome depends on relative bargaining skills and other factors in the bargaining process. Figure 1: The box diagram in a simple exchange model
  • 18. Consider now the case in which each country has many traders and therefore the economy is a competitive one—each trader is a price taker and the market prices are influenced by the market excess demand or supply of the goods. A representative trader facing market prices tries to maximize their utility subject to the budget constraint. If all traders in a country are identical, 7 then the home country’s traders will chooseD1 andD2 to maximizeU (D1;D2) subject to (3), or equivalently pD1 +D2 = pS1 +S2: (14) Each solvedDj is a function ofp andpS1 + S2, which is the national income in terms of G2. 3 With S1 andS2 fixed in the present model, the national income is also a function ofp, which is the terms of trade. Thus,Dj = Dj (p) : Similarly, for F,D � j = D � j (p
  • 19. �) : Under free trade,p = p�: The equilibriump� is determined by the market clearing conditions.4 As already discussed, Walras’ Law implies that only one of the market equilibrium conditions in (7) and (8) is needed for this purpose. Take, for example, the G1 market clearing condition (7): D1 (p)+D � 1 (p �) = S1 +S � 1: (15) This equation can be used to solve for the equilibrium terms of tradep�(= p): Clearly, the equilib- rium p� is determined byS1 + S � 1 and the underlying preferences of both countries. Fig. 2 is the graphical representation of (15). Alternatively, one can use the export and import functions to solve for the equilibriump�: From (15), we can rewrite (9) asX (p) = M� (p�) ; which can be solved for the same solution set. Fig. 3 shows this alternative way of determining the equilibrium terms
  • 20. of trade. 3To solve this problem, set up the Lagrangian functionL(D1;D2;�) = U (D1;D2) + �(pS1 +S2 �pD1 �D2) ; where � is the Lagrange multiplier. By embedding the constraint into the La- grangian function and introducing the new variable�, the original constrained maximization problem is equivalent to maximizing the unconstrainedL function with respect to the three variables,D1; D2 and �: The first-order conditions are:@[email protected] = U1 � �p = 0; @[email protected] = U2 � � = 0 [email protected][email protected]� = pS1 + S2 � pD1 � D2 = 0; whereUj � @[email protected]: These three conditions are used to solve for the three variables. Note that from the first two conditions, we haveU1=U2 = p; namely, the marginal utility ratio is the price ratio at the optimum. Let the utility attained at the optimum be�U: From the indifference curveU (D1;D2) = �U; we haveU1dD1 + U2dD2 = 0; which implies that the marginal rate of substitution (MRS)�dD2=dD1jU=�U is equal toU1=U2; and hence is equal top: 4In the pure exchange model with no specification of the money markets, the nominal money prices(p�1;p � 2) are indeterminate. This is seen by noting that if(p�1;p � 2) is a solution, then(�p � 1;�p
  • 21. � 2) is also a solution for any� > 0: By changing all money prices by the same proportion, the budget constraints are unaffected, and the money income is also changed by the same proportion. Thus, the chosen demands will remain unchanged and the chosen trade volumes will also be unchanged; here only the relative price matters. 8 Figure 2: The determination of the equilibrium terms of trade p=p* * 1 1S S+ ( ) ( )*1 1 *p DD p+ 0 * * 1 1 1 1, SD D S+ + p, p* 3.2 The Offer Curves Consider Fig. 4, in whichE is the endowment point of the home country. The budget constraint in (3) are lines that go through pointE under different prices.
  • 22. Ifp� = a; the highest utility attainable under the budget lineEK is Ua with the preferred consumption point atK: Similarly, at p� = b; the preferred consumption point isN: The collection of all the preferred consumption points for different values ofp� is the curveEKN: This curve, viewed from the origin0; is a price consumption curve; if viewed from the new originE; it is the offer curve. Atp� = a; H will offer EY of G1 for YK of G2. At p� = b; H will offer EZ of G1 for ZN of G2. The offer curve thus portrays the utility-maximizing bundle of desired trade for various values ofp�: If the price line is sufficiently flat (the relative price of G1 is sufficiently low), the desired trading point moves to the south-east region ofE: In this case, the trade pattern is reversed—H will want to export G2 and import G1. Depending upon the indifference map, the offer curve can have quite different shapes. 9 Figure 3: p=p*
  • 23. ( )X p ( )* *M p 0 *,X M p, p* Fig. 5 plots the offer curve in the(X;M) axes. It is the mirror- image of Fig. 4 withE as the new origin. This curve shows thereciprocal demands schedule, which demonstrates that a nation’s exports are for the purpose of obtaining imports. There are no free meals on earth. As the terms of tradep� moves froma to b; the optimal trading point moves fromK to N: LinesEa andEb are generated by the balance-of-trade equilibrium condition given in (4). An increase inp�, which is the same as an increase inM=X, gives the home country improved terms of trade, in which a unit of exports can be exchanged for more units of imports. 3.3 Determination and Stability of a Trading Equilibrium The foreign country’s offer curve is the mirror image of the home’s, with the horizontal axisM�(in G1) and the vertical axisX� (in G2). By superimposing the
  • 24. home and foreign offer curves in one graph, we obtain Fig. 6. Equilibrium occurs at the intersection pointT of the two offer curves0O and 0O�: At T; X = M�, andM = X�, both markets are cleared. Desired exports of one country are matched by 10 Figure 4: Derivation of the offer curve the desired imports of the other. Trade can therefore take place at theequilibrium terms of trade p�: Clearly, at the trading pointT; both countries’ balances of trade are in equilibrium:p�X = M = X� = p�M�: The attainment of the equilibriump� in a competitive economy should be addressed further. Suppose that temporarily the price line is0a as shown in Fig. 6. H’s chosen trading point isK and F’s isJ: In this case, we haveM� > X andM < X�: G1 has excess demand in the world market and G2 excess supply. It is reasonable to hypothesize that if a good is in excess demand, its price
  • 25. will rise, and if in excess supply, its price will fall. If trade can only take place given a contract that matches the desired trading volumes of both traders, then at the price line0a, the desired trading volumes wouldn’t match, and therefore, the competitive market force will push upp�1 and push downp�2: Thus, the price ratiop � (� p�1=p�2) will go up. This process will continue as long as the 11 Figure 5: The offer curve ZY N X M E a K O
  • 26. b markets are not cleared. Eventually, the equilibrium price line0T is reached, and the equilibrium terms of tradep�are established. From the offer curve analysis, one can easily verify Walras’ Law. At the price line0a; the price ratio isp�a1 =p �a 2 : G1 has a world excess demand in the amount ofM ��X, and G2 has a world excess supply ofX� �M: The slope of the0a line isp�a1 =p�a2 , which is equal to(X� �M)=(M� �X) : Thus,p�a1 (M � �X) = p�a2 (X� �M) ; or equivalently,p�a1 (M� �X) + p�a2 (M �X�) = 0; is Walras’ Law as already shown in (12). 3.4 The Possibility of Multiple Equilibria As previously mentioned, since the shape of an offer curve depends on the indifference map and the initial endowments, it can exhibit strange shapes. Fig. 7 illustrates a case of multiple equilibria. 12
  • 27. Figure 6: Trading equilibrium J V W a ZY T X, M* M, X* 0 K O p* O* It has three equilibrium terms of trade. It can be verified that if the price line is in the conep�0p�00 or below it, the price ratio will converge towardp�0. But if it is in the conep�00p�000 or above it,
  • 28. the price ratio will converge towardp�000. Thus,p�0 andp�000 are stable butp�00 is unstable. A slight disturbance of the price away fromp�00 will accelerate the price divergence toward eitherp�0 or p�000: 4 Example: Price Formation in P.O.W. Camps R. A. Radford was an Allied prisoner of war in Italian and German prison camps during WWII. In Radford(1945), he documents how markets developed among prisoners based on the allocations of Red Cross parcels, which were quite regularly and evenly distributed among prisoners. For example, a nonsmoker would find it beneficial to trade his cigarettes for canned foods from smok- ers. This was an economy with no production, but exchanges still took place. Different national 13 Figure 7: Multiple equilibria * 'p * '''p O*
  • 29. O '''T 'T ''T X, M* M, X* 0 * ''p groups in different camps showed different relative prices— coffee was relatively more expensive in French camps and tea in English ones. Cigarettes evolved as a medium of exchange. A trader starting with a fixed bundle of goods gained by trading (arbitraging) through different camps. Eventually, equilibrium market prices quoted in terms of cigarettes were observed across camps. Since the medium of exchange itself was a consumable commodity, the phenomena of inflation and deflation due to currency creation and destruction were observed during a rationing cycle. To reap better terms of trade, some nonsmokers would wait until a
  • 30. later stage of the rationing cycle to sell his cigarettes when cigarettes became relatively scarce. Coffee shops and laundry services were established by the prisoners in the camps, turning a pure exchange economy into one with production! 14 5 The Optimality of a Competitive Trading World In a competitive world economy, each country’s traders observe given world prices while trying to maximize their utilities subject to their budget constraints. By assuming the existence of a social utility function, we have derived the offer curves for both countries. The optimality of the competitive economy can be further illuminated by adding the offer curves in the box diagram, as shown in Fig. 8. PointT is the trading point as it is the intersection of the two offer curves EO andEO�: SinceT is on H’s offer curve, there is a home country’s indifference curveUT that is tangent to the price linep (= p�) : Similarly, there is a foreign country’s indifference curve
  • 31. U�T that is also tangent to thep � line. By trading to pointT from the endowment pointE; the home country’s utility level increases fromU0 to UT; and the foreign country’s increases from U�0 to U � T : Both countries move to a higher indifference curve. The gains from trade are clearly revealed. Moreover, since pointT is the tangent point ofUT andU � T ; it must be on the contract curve. Thus, free trade is Pareto efficient. In addition, a free trade equilibrium must be in the core of the economy. In the case of market power, as discussed earlier in the bargaining case, the core is represented by the line segmentAA�: Economic theory on the core shows that as the number of agents in the market increases, the core shrinks in size and approximates the set of competitive equilibria. Thus, a competitive economy is Pareto efficient. 6 Appendix 6.1 The Marshall-Lerner Condition The condition for the stability of an equilibrium is related to
  • 32. how excess demands adjust when there is a change in the price ratio. The adjustment can be expressed in terms of the price elasticity of import demand. Let the home and foreign country’s price elasticities of import demand be respectively defined as " � � � 1 p � dM Md � 1 p �; "� � �p�dM� M�dp� : (16) 15 Figure 8: Free trade is Pareto efficient
  • 34. TU *p p= *O O Note thatM is in G2, and its relative price (in terms of G1) is1=p (� p2=p1) in the home country. Likewise, M� is in G1, and its relative price (in terms of G2) isp� in the foreign country. The negative sign attached to both definitions makes both elasticities positive in the normal sense. Recall that the world excess demand for G1 isE1 = M � �X: Using the home country’s balance- of-trade equilibrium condition (4), we have E1 = M � �M=p�: (17) Under free trade,p = p�; and therefore,M is a function of1=p�, or equivalently, a function of p�. Thus,E1 is also a function ofp � and can be expressed asE1 (p �) : Stability arises if a small 16
  • 35. increase inp� at the equilibrium point results in a decrease inE1 so thatE1 becomes negative (or equivalently, a world excess supply is generated). This ensures that the market force will pull p� back to its initial equilibrium.5 This is equivalent to requiring that theE1 (p �) function be negatively sloped in the neighborhood of the equilibrium point: E01 (p �) < 0: (18) Thus, from (17), we obtain dM� dp� � p�dM=dp� �M (p�) 2 < 0; which implies � p�dM� M�dp� +
  • 36. dM M�dp� > M p�M� : (19) At the equilibrium point,E1 = 0 and, therefore,M � = M=p�: Thus, dM M�dp� = p�dM Mdp� = � � 1 p� � dM Md � 1 p� � = � �
  • 37. 1 p � dM Md � 1 p � = " and M p�M� = 1: (20) Using (19) and (20), the local stability condition (18) is equivalent to "+"� > 1: (21) This is the Marshall-Lerner condition —the sum of the price elasticities of both countries’ de- mands for imports must be greater than one for the trading system to be locally stable. The Marshall-Lerner condition appears in a number of trade models. Applying it to the de- valuation model, the Marshall-Lerner condition ensures that a devaluation of a nation’s currency improves its balance of trade. 5The adjustment process can be hypothesized as_p� = kE1 (p
  • 38. �) ; wherek is the speed of adjustment. For this differential equation to have a stable solution, it is required that its characteristic root have a negative real part. 17 6.2 Graphical Representation of the Price Elasticity of Import Demand The price elasticity of import demand is a very important variable in the theory and policy of trade. It can be measured nicely by the use of the offer curve. Consider the home offer curve shown in Fig. 9. Under free trade,p� = p: At p; the desired trading point isT; the desiredM is TN and the desiredX is 0N: Draw a tangent line atT to the offer curve0O with the intercept on the horizontal axis at pointI. Recall that" � �( 1 p)dM Md(1p) = pdM Mdp : Using the home balance-of-trade equilibrium condition (4), we havedp = dp� = d(M=X) = (XdM �MdX)=X2: It follows that
  • 39. " = dM Xdp = XdM (XdM �MdX) = X X �M dX dM : (22) At point T; the slope of the offer curve isdM=dX = TN=IN: Thus,dX=dM = IN=TN: Using 0N � IN = 0I; we obtain " = 0N 0I : (23) At T; the import demand is elastic since" > 1: If point T is at a point on the offer curve that has a vertical tangent line, then" = 1: If the offer curve bends back such that the tangent line is
  • 40. negatively sloped, then" < 1: 6.3 The Price Elasticity of the Supply of Exports Imports and exports are related by the offer curve. Their respective price elasticities are naturally linked to each other. To obtain their precise relationship, lete ande� be the home and foreign countries’ price elasticities of the supply of exports, respectively: e � pdX Xdp ; e� � � 1 p� � dX� X�d � 1 p� �: (24) 18
  • 41. Figure 9: " = 0N=0I I N X M 0 p T O Under free trade,p = p�: Thus, the balance-of-trade equilibrium condition (4) can be written as pX = M. It follows thatX +pdX=dp = X +eX = dM=dp = "X by (22), which implies e = "�1: (25) Similarly, we have e� = "� �1: (26) A country’s export supply elasticity is its import demand elasticity minus one. 19
  • 42. 7 Reference Radford, R. A. (1945), "The Economic Organization of a P.O.W. Camp,"Economica12, 189-201. 8 Exercises 1. Using the numerical example given in (1), try to sell G2 from H to F and sell G1 from F to H. Are these trades profitable? 2. Let H be the U.S. and F be the U.K. and let the U.S. foreign exchange rate bee dollars per pound sterling. (a) Assume that initiallye = 1 ($1 = $1) : If the autarkic price matrix is 2 64 p1 p�1 p2 p � 2 3 75 = 2 64 6 8 1 2 3 75 ; what are the autarkic prices in the U.K. expressed in terms
  • 43. of dollars? Can the U.K. export any good? (b) If the pound is devalued and the newe = 0:1 ($1 = $0:1); can the U.S. export any good? (c) What pattern of trade do you obtain in (a) and (b) above? (d) Is the pattern of trade affected by the value ofe in the barter exchange model? 3. If inflation is across the board in a country affecting every good’s price by the same propor- tion, will it affect the pattern of trade in the barter exchange model? 4. Fig. 3 uses the G1 market clearing condition (9) to find the equilibriump�: Plot a similar figure using the G2 market clearing condition in (10). Pay special attention to the labeling of the price axis. 5. In Fig. 6, if a disequilibrium price ratio, say0b; is above the pointT; which good has a world excess demand and which has a world excess supply? Deduce the direction of movements 20
  • 44. of the disequilibrium price ratiop�b1 =p �b 2 . 6. Prove that in Fig. 7,p�0 andp�000 are stable butp�00 is unstable. 7. In a pure exchange economy, there are two goods, 1 and 2, and two countries, Home and Foreign, having the endowment vectors(S1;S2) = (10;0) and(S � 1;S � 2) = (0;10) and the utility functionsU = D 1 4 1 D 3 4 2 andU � = D�1D � 2; respectively. (a) Derive both goods’ world excess demand functions. (b) Show that both world excess demand functions are functions of only the relative prices
  • 45. p = p1=p2 or 1=p = p2=p1: (c) Solve the equilibrium terms of tradep: (d) Prove the Walras law in this model. 8. " is defined as�( 1 p)dM Md(1p) : Prove that" is also equal topdM Mdp : 9. Assume free trade and the two countries’ import functions areM = 2 � 1 p ��0:4 andM� = 3(p�) �0:8 : Is this trading system stable? Why? (Hint: check to see if the Marshall-Lerner condition is satisfied.) 10. Assume that the home country’s offer curve isM = f (X) = 5X2: If the equilibrium terms
  • 46. of trade arep� = 10; what are the equilibriumX andM? (Hint: use the balance of trade equilibrium conditionp�X = M.) 21 IntroductionThe Determinants of Barter TradesA Simple Model of Trade with Fixed Initial EndowmentsThe Gains from Trade in a Pure Exchange World EconomyThe Offer CurvesDetermination and Stability of a Trading EquilibriumThe Possibility of Multiple EquilibriaExample: Price Formation in P.O.W. CampsThe Optimality of a Competitive Trading WorldAppendixThe Marshall-Lerner ConditionGraphical Representation of the Price Elasticity of Import DemandThe Price Elasticity of the Supply of ExportsReferenceExercises