SlideShare a Scribd company logo
1 of 225
Corruption, Norms, and Legal Enforcement: Evidence from
Diplomatic Parking Tickets
Author(s): Raymond Fisman and Edward Miguel
Source: Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 115, No. 6
(December 2007), pp. 1020-1048
Published by: The University of Chicago Press
Stable URL: http://www.jstor.org/stable/10.1086/527495 .
Accessed: 25/03/2015 17:53
Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the
Terms & Conditions of Use, available at .
http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp
.
JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars,
researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide
range of
content in a trusted digital archive. We use information
technology and tools to increase productivity and facilitate new
forms
of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please
contact [email protected]
.
The University of Chicago Press is collaborating with JSTOR to
digitize, preserve and extend access to Journal
of Political Economy.
http://www.jstor.org
This content downloaded from 164.107.70.42 on Wed, 25 Mar
2015 17:53:25 PM
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
http://www.jstor.org/action/showPublisher?publisherCode=ucpr
ess
http://www.jstor.org/stable/10.1086/527495?origin=JSTOR-pdf
http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp
http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp
1020
[ Journal of Political Economy, 2007, vol. 115, no. 6]
� 2007 by The University of Chicago. All rights reserved.
0022-3808/2007/11506-0002$10.00
Corruption, Norms, and Legal Enforcement:
Evidence from Diplomatic Parking Tickets
Raymond Fisman
Columbia University and National Bureau of Economic
Research
Edward Miguel
University of California, Berkeley and National Bureau of
Economic Research
We study cultural norms and legal enforcement in controlling
cor-
ruption by analyzing the parking behavior of United Nations
officials
in Manhattan. Until 2002, diplomatic immunity protected UN
dip-
lomats from parking enforcement actions, so diplomats’ actions
were
constrained by cultural norms alone. We find a strong effect of
cor-
ruption norms: diplomats from high-corruption countries (on the
basis of existing survey-based indices) accumulated
significantly more
unpaid parking violations. In 2002, enforcement authorities
acquired
the right to confiscate diplomatic license plates of violators.
Unpaid
violations dropped sharply in response. Cultural norms and
(partic-
ularly in this context) legal enforcement are both important
deter-
minants of corruption.
We thank Stefano Dellvigna, Seema Jayachandran, Dean Yang,
Luigi Zingales, and sem-
inar participants at the Harvard Development Economics Lunch,
Harvard Behavioral
Economics Seminar, Harvard Kennedy School of Government,
Harvard Political Economy
discussion group, University of Michigan, London School of
Economics, University of
Southern California, Stockholm University, University of
California, Berkeley, Northwest-
ern University, University of Hawaii, Syracuse University,
Harvard Business School, World
Bank, University of Toronto, two anonymous referees, and
Steve Levitt for helpful sug-
gestions. Daniel Hartley, Adam Sacarny, and Sarath Sanga
provided superb research as-
sistance. We thank Gillian Sorensen for helpful discussions. We
are especially grateful to
the New York City Department of Finance for providing us with
data on parking violations
and National Public Radio for alerting us to the existence of
these data. All errors are
our own.
This content downloaded from 164.107.70.42 on Wed, 25 Mar
2015 17:53:25 PM
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp
corruption, norms, and legal enforcement 1021
I. Introduction
The underlying causes of corruption remain poorly understood
and
widely debated. Yet the study of corruption beyond the realm of
opinion
surveys is still in its infancy, and there is little firm evidence
relating
corruption to real-world causal factors. Notably, both social
norms and
legal enforcement are often mentioned as primary contributors
to cor-
ruption in both the academic literature and the popular press,
yet there
is no evidence beyond the most casual of cross-country
empirics.1
Distinguishing between the effects of social norms and legal
enforce-
ment is confounded by problems of identification: societies that
collec-
tively place less importance on rooting out corruption, and thus
have
weak anticorruption social norms, may simultaneously have less
legal
enforcement. Understanding the relative importance of these
potential
causes of corruption is of central importance in reforming
public in-
stitutions to improve governance and in the current debate in
foreign
aid policy. The World Bank emphasizes effectiveness of legal
enforce-
ment, but social reformers have highlighted the importance of
changing
civic norms in anticorruption efforts.2
We develop an empirical approach for evaluating the role of
both
social norms and legal enforcement in corruption by studying
parking
violations among United Nations diplomats living in New York
City.
Mission personnel and their families benefit from diplomatic
immunity,
a privilege that allowed them to avoid paying parking fines
prior to
November 2002. The act of parking illegally fits well with a
standard
definition of corruption, that is, “the abuse of entrusted power
for pri-
vate gain,”3 suggesting that the comparison of parking
violations by
diplomats from different societies serves as a plausible measure
of the
extent of corruption social norms or a corruption “culture.”
This setting has a number of advantages for studying corruption
norms. Most important, our approach avoids the problem of
differential
legal enforcement levels across countries and more generally
strips out
enforcement effects prior to the New York City government’s
enforce-
1 See Lambsdorff (2006) for an overview of findings on the
determinants of corruption
based on cross-country comparisons. Witzel (2005) provides
one of many discussions on
the topic in the popular press. The effects of legal enforcement
on crime in general have
been much examined theoretically, beginning with Becker
(1968). Theories of norms and
corruption are presented in Mauro (2004), which discusses
models of multiple equilibria
in corruption levels that could be interpreted as capturing
corruption culture, and in
Tirole (1996), which develops a model of bureaucratic
collective reputation that also
implies persistent corruption.
2 One successful anticorruption reformer who focused on
changing norms as an element
of reform, and who is well cited in the international media, is
Antanas Mockus, the former
mayor of Bogotá, Colombia (Rockwell 2004).
3 This is the definition used by the leading anticorruption
organization Transparency
International (see
http://ww1.transparency.org/about_ti/mission.html).
This content downloaded from 164.107.70.42 on Wed, 25 Mar
2015 17:53:25 PM
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp
q
Highlight
q
Highlight
q
Highlight
q
Highlight
q
Highlight
q
Highlight
q
Highlight
q
Highlight
q
Highlight
1022 journal of political economy
ment actions of November 2002, since there was essentially no
enforce-
ment of diplomats’ parking violations before this time. We thus
interpret
diplomats’ behavior as reflecting their underlying propensity to
break
rules for private gain when enforcement is not a consideration.
Dip-
lomats to UN missions are also a relatively homogeneous group,
selected
for similar official duties in New York. Additionally, because
UN missions
are overwhelmingly colocated in Midtown Manhattan—87
percent of
missions are located within 1 mile of the UN complex—we
avoid many
concerns of unobserved differences in parking availability
across geo-
graphic settings.
This approach allows us to construct a “revealed preference”
measure
of corruption among government officials across 149 countries,
based
on real rule breaking in parking.4 Corruption levels,
particularly across
countries, have proved challenging to measure objectively
because of
the illicit nature of corrupt activities. In our main empirical
results, we
find that this parking violation corruption measure is strongly
positively
correlated with other (survey-based) country corruption
measures and
that this relationship is robust to conditioning on region fixed
effects,
country income, and a wide range of other controls, including
govern-
ment employee salary measures. This suggests that home
country cor-
ruption norms are an important predictor of propensity to
behave cor-
ruptly among diplomats: those from low-corruption countries
(e.g.,
Norway) behave remarkably well even in situations in which
there are
no legal consequences, whereas those from high-corruption
countries
(e.g., Nigeria) commit many violations. It also goes somewhat
against
the predictions of standard economic models of crime in
situations of
zero legal enforcement (e.g., Becker 1968), which would predict
high
rates of parking violations among all diplomats in the absence
of
enforcement.
The natural experiment of New York City diplomatic parking
privi-
leges also allows for a direct comparison of the effects of norms
versus
enforcement by exploiting a sharp increase in the legal
punishment for
parking violations. Starting in November 2002, New York City
began
stripping the official diplomatic license plates from vehicles
that accu-
mulated more than three unpaid parking violations. This
credible in-
crease in enforcement—the city government made examples of
30 coun-
tries by having their vehicles’ plates stripped in October
20025—led to
immediate and massive declines of approximately 98 percent in
parking
violations (see fig. 1 below). Thus, cultural norms matter for
crime, but
so does enforcement, a finding that resonates with the work of
Becker
4 In this sense, our corruption measure is conceptually similar
to the Economist
magazine’s “Big Mac Index” as a measure of country
purchasing power parity.
5 Refer to Fries (2002) for an example of media coverage.
This content downloaded from 164.107.70.42 on Wed, 25 Mar
2015 17:53:25 PM
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp
q
Highlight
q
Highlight
q
Highlight
q
Highlight
q
Highlight
q
Highlight
q
Highlight
q
Highlight
q
Highlight
q
Highlight
corruption, norms, and legal enforcement 1023
(1968), Levitt (1997, 2004), Di Tella and Schargrodsky (2003),
and
others on the responsiveness of crime to punishment. In our
setting,
the impact of legal enforcement appears larger than the effects
of var-
iation in cultural norms across countries.
The main theoretical implication of these empirical patterns,
taken
together, is that both cultural norms and legal enforcement play
key
roles in government officials’ corruption decisions. They
suggest that
both factors should be taken seriously in debates about the
causes of
corruption and the policy measures to combat it.
Since the parking violations data exist at the individual level for
all
UN mission diplomats present in New York City (numbering
roughly
1,700 at the start of our study period), we can examine how
individual
behavior evolves over time. For diplomats from high-corruption
coun-
tries of origin, a model of convergence to U.S. corruption norms
would
(presumably) predict a decline in the rate of parking violations
over
time, as tenure in the United States increases. By contrast, a
model of
convergence to the “zero-enforcement” norm discussed above
would
imply an increase in violations over time, particularly for
officials from
low-corruption countries. We find evidence that the frequency
of vio-
lations increases with tenure in New York City and that these
increases
are particularly large for diplomats from low-corruption
countries, sug-
gesting that there is partial convergence to the zero-enforcement
norm
over time.
Beyond contributing to the large literature in economics on the
de-
terminants of legal compliance, our work is part of a growing
body of
research on the importance of cultural background in explaining
in-
dividual behavior. Much of this work compares the outcomes
and actions
of immigrant groups from different countries. For example,
Borjas
(2000) finds that home country attributes are predictive of
immigrants’
economic achievement. In the social domain, Fernandez and
Fogli
(2006) show that fertility rates among Americans are correlated
with
fertility in their countries of ancestry. In work also related to
ours, Ichino
and Maggi (2000) study absenteeism and misconduct of
employees at
an Italian bank and find that region of origin within Italy
predicts
shirking.
We also seek to contribute to the growing empirical literature
on
corruption specifically. Other recent empirical research
emphasizes the
importance of developing corruption measures based on real-
world de-
cisions rather than survey responses; see Reinikka and Svensson
(2004)
and Olken (2006) for discussions. This article is the first to our
knowl-
edge to develop a revealed preference measure of corruption
that is
comparable across countries. Finally, the importance of norm
compli-
ance and nonselfish behavior has been documented in the
laboratory
This content downloaded from 164.107.70.42 on Wed, 25 Mar
2015 17:53:25 PM
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp
q
Highlight
q
Highlight
q
Highlight
q
Highlight
q
Highlight
1024 journal of political economy
(see, e.g., Ledyard 1995), and more recently Levitt (2006)
provides
evidence on norms of nonselfish behavior in the field.
The rest of the article proceeds as follows: Section II describes
the
diplomatic parking situation in New York City and the
violations data,
Section III discusses the rest of the data set, Section IV contains
the
empirical results, and Section V presents conclusions.
II. Diplomatic Parking Violations in New York City
Diplomatic representatives to the United Nations and their
families are
given immunity from prosecution or lawsuits in the United
States. The
original intent of these laws was to protect diplomats from
mistreatment
abroad, especially in countries not on friendly terms with the
home
country.6 However, these days diplomatic immunity is more
commonly
viewed as the “best free parking pass in town” (BBC News
1998). Dip-
lomatic vehicles in New York possess license plates tagged with
the letter
D, which signals diplomatic status.7 While these vehicles may
be ticketed,
the car’s registrant is shielded from any punishment for
nonpayment
of the ticket. Thus one immediate implication of diplomatic
immunity—
not just in New York, but also in most other capitals (e.g.,
London [BBC
News 1998], Paris [Agence Presse–France 2005], and Seoul
[Korea Times
1999])—has been that it allows diplomats to park illegally but
never
suffer the threat of legal punishment, leaving a “paper trail” of
the illegal
acts (see http://www.state.gov/m/ds/immunities/c9127.htm). To
illus-
trate the magnitude of the problem, between November 1997
and the
end of 2002 in New York City, diplomats accumulated over
150,000
unpaid parking tickets, resulting in outstanding fines of more
than $18
million.
The New York City parking violations data are at the level of
the
individual unpaid violation.8 Drivers have 30 days to pay a
ticket before
it goes into default, at which point an additional penalty is
levied (gen-
erally 110 percent of the initial fine). Diplomats then receive an
addi-
tional 70 days to pay the ticket plus this penalty before it is
recorded
in our data set as an unpaid violation in default. The
information on
each violation includes the license plate number; the name and
country
of origin of the car’s registrant; the date, time, and location of
the
6 While the origins of diplomatic protection date back many
centuries, the current
incarnation is found in the 1961 Vienna Convention on
Diplomatic Relations. See
http://www.un.int/usa/host_dip.htm for the full text.
7 Note that while the vehicle’s diplomatic status is revealed by
the license plate, the
country codes denoting particular countries are unrelated to
country names; e.g., the
code (at the start of the plate number) for Mozambique is QS
and the code for Nigeria
is JF.
8 We gratefully acknowledge the New York City Department of
Finance, in particular
Sam Miller and Gerald Koszner, for compiling these data.
This content downloaded from 164.107.70.42 on Wed, 25 Mar
2015 17:53:25 PM
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp
q
Highlight
q
Highlight
q
Highlight
q
Highlight
q
Highlight
corruption, norms, and legal enforcement 1025
violation; the fine and penalty levied; and the amount paid (if
any).
The most common violation in our data was parking in a No
Standing—
Loading Zone (43 percent of violations), which is typically
parking in
someone else’s driveway or business entrance. The remainder
were
spread across a range of violation types that imply varying
degrees of
social harm:9 fines for expired meters accounted for 6 percent
of the
total, double-parking 5 percent, and parking in front of a fire
hydrant
7 percent, for instance. Also note that in 20 percent of
violations the
registrant is the mission itself, signifying an official rather than
personal
vehicle. While the majority of violations are located within a
mile of
either the country’s UN mission or the UN complex, many are
com-
mitted in other parts of the city. We return to the issue of
violation
location below. The total period of coverage in our data set is
November
24, 1997, to November 21, 2005. (Refer to the Data Appendix
for more
on the data set.)
A crucial change in legal enforcement took place in October
2002,
when the State Department gave New York City permission to
revoke
the official diplomatic plates of vehicles with three or more
outstanding
unpaid violations (Steinhauer 2002). In addition, the Clinton-
Schumer
Amendment (named after the two New York senators), put in
place at
the same time, allowed the city to petition the State Department
to have
110 percent of the total amount due deducted from U.S. foreign
aid
to the offending diplomats’ country, although this latter
punishment
was never invoked in practice (Singleton 2004).
In constructing our data set, we generate separate measures of
the
extent of unpaid violations for the pre-enforcement (November
1997–
October 2002) and postenforcement (November 2002–November
2005)
periods. In each case, we employ the total number of unpaid
diplomatic
parking violations for a particular country. In order to control
for base-
line mission size, we calculate the total number of UN
permanent mis-
sion staff with diplomatic privileges using the UN Blue Book
for May
1998. Published twice annually, the Blue Book lists all UN
mission staff,
as well as their official titles. We additionally use UN Blue
Books for
1997–2005 to track the UN tenure of individual diplomats.
Fortunately,
the Blue Books generally use consistent spellings across
editions, facil-
itating automated matching across time. In most cases, the
spelling and
format were also consistent with the names in the parking
violations
data; the algorithm automatically matched 61 percent of
diplomats in
the violations database. The first Blue Book we use is from
January 1997,
9 Almost all parking violations in the data set resulted in fines
of US$55, making it
impossible to assess the extent of social damage by violations’
relative prices.
This content downloaded from 164.107.70.42 on Wed, 25 Mar
2015 17:53:25 PM
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp
q
Highlight
1026 journal of political economy
and we use this as our start date for calculating tenure at the
United
Nations.10
We obtained data on the number of diplomatic license plates
regis-
tered to each mission from the U.S. State Department’s Office
of Foreign
Missions, and we use these data as a control variable in some
specifi-
cations. Unfortunately, these data are available only for 2006,
though
we were assured that the numbers are largely stable over
time.11
Table 1 presents the annual number of violations per diplomat
by
country during the pre-enforcement period (November 1997–
October
2002) and the postenforcement period (November 2002–
November
2005), along with the total number of diplomats in May 1998.
Overall,
the basic pattern accords reasonably well with common
perceptions of
corruption across countries. The worst parking violators—the 10
worst
(in order) are Kuwait, Egypt, Chad, Sudan, Bulgaria,
Mozambique, Al-
bania, Angola, Senegal, and Pakistan—all rank poorly in cross-
country
corruption rankings (described below), with the exception of
Kuwait.
The raw correlation between the country corruption rankings
and pre-
enforcement parking violations per diplomat is �0.18, and that
between
the corruption ranking and postenforcement violations per
capita is
�0.24. While many of the countries with zero violations accord
well with
intuition (e.g., the Scandinavian countries, Canada, and Japan),
there
are a number of surprises. Some of these are countries with very
small
missions (e.g., Burkina Faso and the Central African Republic),
and a
few others have high rates of parking violations but do pay off
the fines
(these are Bahrain, Malaysia, Oman, and Turkey; we return to
this issue
below). The smallest missions may plausibly have fewer
violations since
each mission is given two legal parking spaces at the United
Nations,
and this may suffice if the country has very few diplomats.
Figure 1 plots the total violations per month during November
1997–
November 2005. There are two clear declines in the number of
viola-
tions. The first comes in September 2001, corresponding to the
period
following the World Trade Center attack. The second and
extremely
pronounced decline coincides with increased legal enforcement
of dip-
lomatic parking violators.
10 That is, we cannot distinguish among arrival times pre-1997,
and all individuals in-
cluded in the January 1997 Blue Book are coded as arriving in
that month. As a robustness
check, we also limit the sample only to diplomats who were not
yet present in New York
in the 1997 Blue Book (reducing the sample slightly), which
allows us to more accurately
capture arrival date.
11 We thank Murray Smith of the U.S. Office of Foreign
Services for these data and for
many useful conversations.
This content downloaded from 164.107.70.42 on Wed, 25 Mar
2015 17:53:25 PM
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp
q
Highlight
q
Highlight
q
Highlight
q
Highlight
q
Highlight
q
Highlight
T
A
B
L
E
1
A
ve
ra
g
e
U
n
pa
id
A
n
n
u
al
N
ew
Yo
rk
C
it
y
Pa
rk
in
g
V
io
la
ti
o
n
s
pe
r
D
ip
lo
m
at
,N
o
ve
m
be
r
19
97
to
N
o
ve
m
be
r
20
05
Pa
rk
in
g
V
io
la
ti
on
s
R
an
k
C
ou
n
tr
y
N
am
e
V
io
la
ti
on
s
pe
r
D
ip
lo
m
at
,
Pr
e-
en
fo
rc
em
en
t
(1
1/
19
97
–1
1/
20
02
)
V
io
la
ti
on
s
pe
r
D
ip
lo
m
at
,
Po
st
en
fo
rc
em
en
t
(1
1/
20
02
–1
1/
20
05
)
U
N
M
is
si
on
D
ip
lo
m
at
s
in
19
98
C
or
ru
pt
io
n
In
de
x,
19
98
C
ou
n
tr
y
C
od
e
1
K
uw
ai
t
24
9.
4
.1
5
9
�
1.
07
K
W
T
2
E
gy
pt
14
1.
4
.3
3
24
.2
5
E
G
Y
3
C
h
ad
12
5.
9
.0
0
2
.8
4
T
C
D
4
Su
da
n
12
0.
6
.3
7
7
.7
5
SD
N
5
B
ul
ga
ri
a
11
9.
0
1.
64
6
.5
0
B
G
R
6
M
oz
am
bi
qu
e
11
2.
1
.0
7
5
.7
7
M
O
Z
7
A
lb
an
ia
85
.5
1.
85
3
.9
2
A
L
B
8
A
n
go
la
82
.7
1.
71
9
1.
05
A
G
O
9
Se
n
eg
al
80
.2
.2
1
11
.4
5
SE
N
10
Pa
ki
st
an
70
.3
1.
21
13
.7
6
PA
K
11
Iv
or
y
C
oa
st
68
.0
.4
6
10
.3
5
C
IV
12
Z
am
bi
a
61
.2
.1
5
9
.5
6
Z
M
B
13
M
or
oc
co
60
.8
.4
0
17
.1
0
M
A
R
14
E
th
io
pi
a
60
.4
.6
2
10
.2
5
E
T
H
15
N
ig
er
ia
59
.4
.4
4
25
1.
01
N
G
A
16
Sy
ri
a
53
.3
1.
36
12
.5
8
SY
R
17
B
en
in
50
.4
6.
50
8
.7
6
B
E
N
18
Z
im
ba
bw
e
46
.2
.8
6
14
.1
3
Z
W
E
19
C
am
er
oo
n
44
.1
2.
86
8
1.
11
C
M
R
20
M
on
te
n
eg
ro
an
d
Se
rb
ia
38
.5
.0
5
6
.9
7
YU
G
21
B
ah
ra
in
38
.2
.6
5
7
�
.4
1
B
H
R
22
B
ur
un
di
38
.2
.1
1
3
.8
0
B
D
I
This content downloaded from 164.107.70.42 on Wed, 25 Mar
2015 17:53:25 PM
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp
1028
T
A
B
L
E
1
(C
on
tin
ue
d
)
Pa
rk
in
g
V
io
la
ti
on
s
R
an
k
C
ou
n
tr
y
N
am
e
V
io
la
ti
on
s
pe
r
D
ip
lo
m
at
,
Pr
e-
en
fo
rc
em
en
t
(1
1/
19
97
–1
1/
20
02
)
V
io
la
ti
on
s
pe
r
D
ip
lo
m
at
,
Po
st
en
fo
rc
em
en
t
(1
1/
20
02
–1
1/
20
05
)
U
N
M
is
si
on
D
ip
lo
m
at
s
in
19
98
C
or
ru
pt
io
n
In
de
x,
19
98
C
ou
n
tr
y
C
od
e
23
M
al
i
37
.9
.5
2
5
.5
8
M
L
I
24
In
do
n
es
ia
36
.5
.7
3
25
.9
5
ID
N
25
G
ui
n
ea
35
.2
.5
9
5
.5
7
G
N
B
26
B
os
n
ia
-H
er
ze
go
vi
n
a
34
.9
.1
1
6
.3
5
B
IH
27
So
ut
h
A
fr
ic
a
34
.5
.5
0
19
�
.4
2
Z
A
F
28
Sa
ud
i
A
ra
bi
a
34
.2
.5
2
12
�
.3
5
SA
U
29
B
an
gl
ad
es
h
33
.4
.2
9
8
.4
0
B
G
D
30
B
ra
zi
l
30
.3
.2
3
33
�
.1
0
B
R
A
31
Si
er
ra
L
eo
n
e
25
.9
1.
14
4
.7
2
SL
E
32
A
lg
er
ia
25
.6
1.
36
13
.7
0
D
Z
A
33
T
h
ai
la
n
d
24
.8
.9
8
13
.2
6
T
H
A
34
K
az
ak
h
st
an
21
.4
.2
5
9
.8
6
K
A
Z
35
M
au
ri
ti
us
20
.7
.0
8
4
�
.2
0
M
U
S
36
N
ig
er
20
.2
2.
51
3
.8
8
N
E
R
37
C
ze
ch
R
ep
ub
lic
19
.1
.0
0
7
�
.3
5
C
Z
E
38
L
es
ot
h
o
19
.1
.2
2
6
�
.0
3
L
SO
39
B
ot
sw
an
a
18
.7
.2
5
8
�
.5
3
B
W
A
40
B
h
ut
an
18
.6
.2
6
5
�
.4
6
B
T
N
41
Sr
i
L
an
ka
17
.4
.0
0
5
.2
4
L
K
A
42
C
h
ile
16
.7
.2
1
14
�
1.
20
C
H
L
43
Tu
n
is
ia
16
.7
.6
2
11
�
.1
1
T
U
N
44
N
ep
al
16
.7
.0
5
6
.5
9
N
PL
45
Ir
an
15
.9
.0
2
20
.6
3
IR
N
46
Fi
ji
15
.7
.3
3
3
�
.2
0
FJ
I
47
It
al
y
14
.8
.8
0
16
�
1.
00
IT
A
48
L
ib
er
ia
13
.7
.8
7
6
1.
44
L
B
R
This content downloaded from 164.107.70.42 on Wed, 25 Mar
2015 17:53:25 PM
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp
1029
49
M
al
aw
i
13
.2
.0
5
6
.5
0
M
W
I
50
Pa
ra
gu
ay
13
.2
.5
5
6
.9
7
PR
Y
51
R
w
an
da
13
.1
1.
20
3
.5
5
R
W
A
52
U
kr
ai
n
e
13
.1
.7
0
14
.8
9
U
K
R
53
Sp
ai
n
12
.9
.5
2
15
�
1.
59
E
SP
54
Ph
ili
pp
in
es
11
.7
.0
8
20
.2
6
PH
L
55
G
h
an
a
11
.4
.1
6
10
.4
4
G
H
A
56
M
au
ri
ta
n
ia
11
.3
.2
6
5
.2
9
M
R
T
57
G
ui
n
ea
-B
is
sa
u
10
.9
1.
34
10
.8
2
G
IN
58
E
st
on
ia
10
.7
.4
4
3
�
.4
9
E
ST
59
M
on
go
lia
10
.3
.0
7
5
.2
8
M
N
G
60
A
rm
en
ia
10
.2
.1
6
4
.7
1
A
R
M
61
C
os
ta
R
ic
a
10
.2
.0
7
19
�
.7
1
C
R
I
62
C
om
or
os
10
.1
5.
23
3
.8
0
C
O
M
63
K
am
pu
ch
ea
(C
am
bo
di
a)
10
.0
.0
7
5
1.
27
K
H
M
64
To
go
10
.0
.9
8
5
.4
5
T
G
O
65
V
ie
tn
am
10
.0
.0
4
15
.6
0
V
N
M
66
G
eo
rg
ia
9.
8
.3
7
8
.6
4
G
E
O
67
C
h
in
a
(P
eo
pl
e’
s
R
ep
ub
lic
)
9.
6
.0
7
69
.1
4
C
H
N
68
Ye
m
en
9.
2
.0
8
8
.5
7
YE
M
69
Ve
n
ez
ue
la
9.
2
.1
0
16
.7
7
V
E
N
70
Po
rt
ug
al
8.
9
.7
8
16
�
1.
56
PR
T
71
U
zb
ek
is
ta
n
8.
9
.1
3
5
.9
8
U
Z
B
72
M
ad
ag
as
ca
r
8.
8
.5
7
8
.8
0
M
D
G
73
Ta
n
za
n
ia
8.
4
.7
4
8
.9
5
T
Z
A
74
L
ib
ya
8.
3
.3
3
9
.9
1
L
B
Y
75
K
en
ya
7.
8
.0
4
17
.9
2
K
E
N
76
C
on
go
(B
ra
zz
av
ill
e)
7.
8
.0
5
6
.9
9
C
O
G
77
C
ro
at
ia
6.
6
.1
8
9
.3
3
H
R
V
78
D
jib
ou
ti
6.
5
.0
0
3
.8
0
D
JI
79
Sl
ov
ak
R
ep
ub
lic
6.
5
.1
6
12
.0
8
SV
K
80
Z
ai
re
6.
4
.2
2
6
1.
58
Z
A
R
81
Fr
an
ce
6.
2
.1
4
29
�
1.
75
FR
A
82
In
di
a
6.
2
.5
5
18
.1
7
IN
D
This content downloaded from 164.107.70.42 on Wed, 25 Mar
2015 17:53:25 PM
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp
1030
T
A
B
L
E
1
(C
on
tin
ue
d
)
Pa
rk
in
g
V
io
la
ti
on
s
R
an
k
C
ou
n
tr
y
N
am
e
V
io
la
ti
on
s
pe
r
D
ip
lo
m
at
,
Pr
e-
en
fo
rc
em
en
t
(1
1/
19
97
–1
1/
20
02
)
V
io
la
ti
on
s
pe
r
D
ip
lo
m
at
,
Po
st
en
fo
rc
em
en
t
(1
1/
20
02
–1
1/
20
05
)
U
N
M
is
si
on
D
ip
lo
m
at
s
in
19
98
C
or
ru
pt
io
n
In
de
x,
19
98
C
ou
n
tr
y
C
od
e
83
L
ao
s
6.
2
.0
0
9
.7
0
L
A
O
84
Tu
rk
m
en
is
ta
n
5.
9
.0
0
4
1.
13
T
K
M
85
Pa
pu
a
N
ew
G
ui
n
ea
5.
6
1.
74
3
.7
0
PN
G
86
H
on
du
ra
s
5.
5
.0
0
6
.7
5
H
N
D
87
Sl
ov
en
ia
5.
3
.4
5
8
�
.8
3
SV
N
88
K
yr
gy
zs
ta
n
5.
2
1.
05
5
.6
9
K
G
Z
89
N
ic
ar
ag
ua
4.
9
.4
4
9
.7
5
N
IC
90
U
ru
gu
ay
4.
5
.0
9
11
�
.4
2
U
R
Y
91
Sw
az
ila
n
d
4.
4
.4
7
7
.1
9
SW
Z
92
Ta
jik
is
ta
n
4.
4
.1
6
4
1.
12
T
JK
93
N
am
ib
ia
4.
3
.0
9
11
�
.2
4
N
A
M
94
M
ex
ic
o
4.
0
.0
2
19
.3
9
M
E
X
95
A
rg
en
ti
n
a
4.
0
.3
6
19
.2
2
A
R
G
96
Si
n
ga
po
re
3.
6
.1
6
6
�
2.
50
SG
P
97
R
om
an
ia
3.
6
.3
3
10
.3
8
R
O
M
98
U
ga
n
da
3.
5
.2
3
7
.6
2
U
G
A
99
H
un
ga
ry
3.
3
.0
8
8
�
.6
9
H
U
N
10
0
M
ac
ed
on
ia
3.
3
.1
6
4
.3
0
M
K
D
10
1
B
ol
iv
ia
3.
1
.0
0
9
.4
1
B
O
L
10
2
Pe
ru
3.
1
.3
6
9
.1
7
PE
R
10
3
H
ai
ti
3.
0
.0
4
9
.8
5
H
T
I
10
4
Jo
rd
an
3.
0
.0
0
9
�
.2
1
JO
R
10
5
B
el
ar
us
2.
7
.0
0
8
.6
0
B
L
R
10
6
B
el
gi
um
2.
7
.1
4
14
�
1.
23
B
E
L
10
7
C
yp
ru
s
2.
5
.0
6
11
�
1.
38
C
YP
10
8
G
uy
an
a
2.
3
.1
3
5
.2
6
G
U
Y
This content downloaded from 164.107.70.42 on Wed, 25 Mar
2015 17:53:25 PM
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp
1031
10
9
A
us
tr
ia
2.
2
.5
1
21
�
2.
02
A
U
T
11
0
G
ab
on
2.
2
.2
9
8
.9
0
G
A
B
11
1
R
us
si
a
2.
1
.0
3
86
.6
9
R
U
S
11
2
L
it
h
ua
n
ia
2.
1
.0
5
7
�
.0
7
LT
U
11
3
E
l
Sa
lv
ad
or
1.
7
.2
6
10
.2
7
SL
V
11
4
Po
la
n
d
1.
7
.0
4
17
�
.4
9
PO
L
11
5
G
am
bi
a
1.
5
.2
9
8
.4
9
G
M
B
11
6
M
al
ay
si
a
1.
4
.2
0
13
�
.7
3
M
YS
11
7
Tr
in
id
ad
an
d
To
ba
go
1.
4
.1
6
6
�
.1
3
T
T
O
11
8
L
eb
an
on
1.
4
.0
0
3
.3
2
L
B
N
11
9
G
er
m
an
y
1.
0
.1
0
52
�
2.
21
D
E
U
12
0
E
ri
tr
ea
.8
.0
0
3
�
.4
6
E
R
I
12
1
M
ol
do
va
.7
.0
0
4
.5
1
M
D
A
12
2
K
or
ea
(S
ou
th
)
.4
.1
9
33
�
.1
1
K
O
R
12
3
D
om
in
ic
an
R
ep
ub
lic
.1
.0
0
22
.5
3
D
O
M
12
4
Fi
n
la
n
d
.1
.0
0
18
�
2.
55
FI
N
12
5
G
ua
te
m
al
a
.1
.0
7
9
.6
3
G
T
M
12
6
Sw
it
ze
rl
an
d
.1
.0
0
10
�
2.
58
C
H
E
12
7
N
ew
Z
ea
la
n
d
.1
.0
0
8
�
2.
55
N
Z
L
12
8
U
n
it
ed
K
in
gd
om
.0
.0
1
31
�
2.
33
G
B
R
12
9
N
et
h
er
la
n
ds
.0
.1
0
17
�
2.
48
N
L
D
13
0
U
n
it
ed
A
ra
b
E
m
ir
at
es
.0
.0
0
3
�
.7
8
A
R
E
13
1
A
us
tr
al
ia
.0
.0
3
12
�
2.
21
A
U
S
13
2
A
ze
rb
ai
ja
n
.0
.9
8
5
1.
01
A
Z
E
13
3
B
ur
ki
n
a-
Fa
so
.0
.2
0
5
.5
1
B
FA
13
4
C
en
tr
al
A
fr
ic
an
R
ep
ub
lic
.0
.0
0
3
.5
5
C
A
F
13
5
C
an
ad
a
.0
.0
0
24
�
2.
51
C
A
N
13
6
C
ol
om
bi
a
.0
.0
0
16
.6
1
C
O
L
13
7
D
en
m
ar
k
.0
.0
2
17
�
2.
57
D
N
K
13
8
E
cu
ad
or
.0
.0
0
9
.7
4
E
C
U
13
9
G
re
ec
e
.0
.1
1
21
�
.8
5
G
R
C
14
0
Ir
el
an
d
.0
.0
7
10
�
2.
15
IR
L
14
1
Is
ra
el
.0
.0
9
15
�
1.
41
IS
R
14
2
Ja
m
ai
ca
.0
.0
0
9
.2
6
JA
M
This content downloaded from 164.107.70.42 on Wed, 25 Mar
2015 17:53:25 PM
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp
T
A
B
L
E
1
(C
on
tin
ue
d
)
Pa
rk
in
g
V
io
la
ti
on
s
R
an
k
C
ou
n
tr
y
N
am
e
V
io
la
ti
on
s
pe
r
D
ip
lo
m
at
,
Pr
e-
en
fo
rc
em
en
t
(1
1/
19
97
–1
1/
20
02
)
V
io
la
ti
on
s
pe
r
D
ip
lo
m
at
,
Po
st
en
fo
rc
em
en
t
(1
1/
20
02
–1
1/
20
05
)
U
N
M
is
si
on
D
ip
lo
m
at
s
in
19
98
C
or
ru
pt
io
n
In
de
x,
19
98
C
ou
n
tr
y
C
od
e
14
3
Ja
pa
n
.0
.0
1
47
�
1.
16
JP
N
14
4
L
at
vi
a
.0
.0
0
5
.1
0
LV
A
14
5
N
or
w
ay
.0
.0
0
12
�
2.
35
N
O
R
14
6
O
m
an
.0
.2
6
5
�
.8
9
O
M
N
14
7
Pa
n
am
a
.0
.0
0
8
.2
8
PA
N
14
8
Sw
ed
en
.0
.0
0
19
�
2.
55
SW
E
14
9
Tu
rk
ey
.0
.0
0
25
.0
1
T
U
R
N
o
te
.—
T
h
e
co
rr
up
ti
on
in
de
x
is
fr
om
K
au
fm
an
n
et
al
.
(2
00
5)
.A
h
ig
h
er
sc
or
e
in
th
e
co
rr
up
ti
on
in
de
x
de
n
ot
es
m
or
e
co
rr
up
ti
on
.
This content downloaded from 164.107.70.42 on Wed, 25 Mar
2015 17:53:25 PM
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp
corruption, norms, and legal enforcement 1033
Fig. 1.—Total monthly New York City parking violations by
diplomats, 1997–2005 (ver-
tical axis on log scale).
III. Cross-Country Data
We employ country-level data on economic, political, and social
char-
acteristics and in particular consider data on country corruption
levels
using the measure in Kaufmann, Kraay, and Mastruzzi (2005)
from 1998,
the earliest year with wide country coverage. This is a
composite cor-
ruption index that is essentially the first principal component of
a num-
ber of other commonly used corruption indices, which are
usually sub-
jective measures based on surveys of country experts and
investors. By
definition, therefore, the Kaufmann et al. measure is highly
correlated
with the commonly used indices and is extremely highly
correlated
( ) with the Transparency International ratings from the samer p
0.97
year. For ease of interpretation, we reverse the sign of the
original mea-
sure so that higher values indicate greater corruption. By
construction,
the mean value of this measure across all countries in their
sample is
zero with standard deviation one, and it ranges from �2.6 to
�1.6 in
our slightly restricted sample of countries. The main advantages
of this
country measure are that its method of aggregation is clearly
defined
relative to the Transparency International measure, and it has
broader
country coverage than other indices. Our sample consists of all
countries
that had 1998 populations greater than 500,000 according to the
World
Development Indicators, and for which basic country-level data
were
This content downloaded from 164.107.70.42 on Wed, 25 Mar
2015 17:53:25 PM
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp
q
Highlight
1034 journal of political economy
TABLE 2
Descriptive Statistics
Variable Mean
Standard
Deviation Observations
A. Country-Level Data
Unpaid New York City parking violations:a
11/1997–11/2002 977.9 2,000.9 149
11/2002–11/2005 11.3 18.4 149
Unpaid and paid New York City parking
violations, 11/1997–11/2002a 1,066.2 2,021.4 149
After-hours New York city parking viola-
tions, 11/1997–11/2002 a 40.6 72.7 149
Diplomats in the country UN mission,
1998b 11.8 11.1 149
Number of license plates registered to the
country’s UN mission, 2006c 10.5 14.0 139
Country corruption index, 1998d .01 1.01 149
Log per capita income (1998 US$)e 7.35 1.59 149
Average government wage/country per
capita income, early 1990sf 2.83 2.38 92
Log weighted distance between
populationsg 9.12 .41 149
Log total trade with the United States
(1998 US$)h 20.3 2.7 146
Received U.S. economic aid (indicator),
1998i .69 .46 147
Received U.S. military aid (indicator),
1998i .63 .49 147
B. Diplomat-Level Data
Monthly unpaid New York City parking
violations:a
11/1997–11/2002 .90 3.30 25,123
11/2002–11/2005 .02 .19 15,806
Length of time at the UN mission in New
York City (in months)b 7.7 12.4 40,929
a Source: New York City, Parking Violations Database
(provided to the authors by the New York City Department of
Finance).
b Source: United Nations Blue Books, 1997–2005.
c Source: U.S. Department of State Office of Foreign Missions
(provided to the authors by Deputy Director Murray
Smith).
d Composite index from Kaufmann et al. (2005), but here higher
values indicate more corruption.
e Source: World Development Indicators (2005).
f Source: Schiavo-Campo et al. (1999); exact year differs by
country.
g Source: Mayer and Zignago (2005).
h Source: U.S. International Trade Commission (2006).
i Data from Kuziemko and Werker (2006).
available. Table 2 presents summary statistics for both the
country-level
and diplomat-level variables.
We include a number of other variables that may affect
incentives to
comply with local laws. From the data set used by Kuziemko
and Werker
(2006), we generate an indicator variable denoting whether the
country
received foreign aid from the United States in 1998. We
similarly gen-
erate a pair of indicator variables for military and economic aid,
since
This content downloaded from 164.107.70.42 on Wed, 25 Mar
2015 17:53:25 PM
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp
q
Highlight
q
Highlight
q
Highlight
corruption, norms, and legal enforcement 1035
these two types of aid may reflect different geopolitical
interests: while
economic aid recipients may feel beholden to the United States,
those
receiving military aid are typically countries that the United
States seeks
as strategic allies.
Finally, we include the logarithm of 1998 GDP per capita in
U.S.
dollars (taken from the World Development Indicators) in most
spec-
ifications to control for income effects. Country-level income
per capita
is strongly correlated with corruption and with the rule of law,
and some
argue that income is influenced by underlying corruption levels,
com-
plicating efforts to disentangle corruption effects from income
effects.
As we discuss below, despite this strong correlation, the main
corruption
results are robust to including income controls. Second, we
include the
ratio of government bureaucrats’ salaries to GDP per capita
(using data
from Schiavo-Campo, de Tommaso, and Mukherjee [1999]) for
the early
1990s (exact year differs by country) to account for the
possibility that
bureaucrats occupy different positions in the national income
distribution.
IV. Empirical Results
A count model analysis is appropriate given the dependent
variable, the
total number of unpaid parking violations by country. We focus
on the
negative binomial model (the Poisson model can be rejected at
high
levels of confidence because of overdispersion of the parking
tickets
outcome variable; result not shown). In the main econometric
specifi-
cation for the cross-country analysis, the dependent variable is
Total
Unpaid Parking Violationsit, where i denotes the country. There
are two
time periods t per country, one for the pre-enforcement period
and one
for the postenforcement period. Standard errors are robustly
estimated,
and the disturbance terms for a country are allowed to be
correlated.
The vector of explanatory variables is
′b Corruption � b Enforcement � b Diplomats � X g,1 i 2 it 3 i
i
where Corruption is the 1998 country corruption index;
Enforcement
is an indicator for the post–October 2002 period, when legal
enforce-
ment increased sharply against diplomatic parking violators;
and X is a
vector of other country controls, including the log of 1998 GDP
per
capita, and region fixed effects,12 among others depending on
the
specification.
The New York City unpaid parking violations measure is
robustly
12 United Nations region code data, available at
http://unstats.un.org/unsd/methods/
m49/m49regin.htm, were used to classify countries into the
following regions: (1) North
America (including Caribbean), (2) South America, (3) Europe,
(4) Asia, (5) Oceania,
(6) Africa, and (7) Middle East.
This content downloaded from 164.107.70.42 on Wed, 25 Mar
2015 17:53:25 PM
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp
q
Highlight
q
Highlight
q
Highlight
q
Highlight
q
Highlight
q
Highlight
q
Highlight
q
Highlight
q
Highlight
1036 journal of political economy
positively correlated with the existing subjective country
corruption in-
dex conditional on the number of UN mission diplomats for that
coun-
try in New York City (table 3, regression 1). The relationship is
roughly
linear (fig. 2). The coefficient implies that the increase in the
corruption
index associated with going from a highly corrupt country such
as Ni-
geria (corruption score �1.01) to a largely uncorrupt country
such as
Norway (score �2.35) is associated with a large drop of 48 log
points
# 3.36 p 161 log points, or approximately 80 percent, in the
average
rate of diplomatic parking violations. The result is nearly
unchanged if
Kuwait, the country with the most parking violations per
diplomat, is
dropped from the sample (not shown). Parking violations also
plummet
in the postenforcement period, by over 98 percent on average,
indi-
cating that legal enforcement is also highly influential.
The coefficient estimate on the country corruption index is
robust
to the inclusion of log per capita income (table 3, regression 2).
This
pattern argues strongly against the explanation that richer
countries are
simply able to purchase more parking spots for their diplomats,
in which
case we would expect a weakening of the relationship between
country
corruption and parking violations and a negative coefficient
estimate
on country income, but we find neither. The result is also robust
to
controlling for region fixed effects (regression 3). The Middle
East and
Africa are the regions with the greatest average number of
unpaid park-
ing violations relative to the reference region (North America
and the
Caribbean). The inclusion of higher-order polynomial controls
for in-
come (regression 4) and an interaction between country
corruption
and the postenforcement period (regression 5) also has little
effect on
the partial correlation of the corruption index with parking
violations
committed. The interaction term between country corruption and
the
postenforcement period indicator variable has little predictive
power,
indicating a largely stable relationship across the pre- and
postenforce-
ment periods (see fig. 3).
The results are robust to including the average government
wage
relative to per capita income (table 4, regression 1) and also to
the
number of vehicles registered to each mission (regression 2).13
The
inclusion of paid violations in our parking violations measure
has no
effect on the main results (regression 3), further arguing against
the
possibility that our country corruption measure is picking up an
income
effect rather than a corruption effect.
There is also strong evidence that many violations are not work
re-
lated. We focus on the subset of violations committed between
the night-
time hours of 10:00 p.m. and 6:00 a.m. at a distance of more
than five
13 A specification using fixed effects for the number of
vehicles per mission generates
similar results (not shown).
This content downloaded from 164.107.70.42 on Wed, 25 Mar
2015 17:53:25 PM
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp
q
Highlight
q
Highlight
q
Highlight
q
Highlight
q
Highlight
q
Highlight
TABLE 3
Country Characteristics and Unpaid New York City Parking
Violations,
November 1997 to November 2005
Dependent Variable: Unpaid Parking Violations
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5)
Country corruption index,
1998 .48*** .57*** .57*** .56** .57*
(.18) (.22) (.21) (.28) (.30)
Postenforcement period
indicator (post-11/2002) �4.41*** �4.41*** �4.21***
�4.43*** �4.41***
(.21) (.21) (.13) (.20) (.21)
Country corruption index
# postenforcement
period �.01
(.28)
Diplomats .05** .04** .05*** .05** .04**
(.02) (.02) (.02) (.02) (.02)
Log per capita income
(1998 US$) .06 .09 64.2* .06
(.14) (.14) (36.9) (.14)
Africa region indicator
variable 2.86***
(.48)
Asia region indicator
variable 1.99***
(.50)
Europe region indicator
variable 2.24***
(.55)
Latin America region indi-
cator variable 1.67***
(.56)
Middle East region indica-
tor variable 3.23***
(.60)
Oceania region indicator
variable 1.51**
(.64)
Log per capita income
(1998 US$) polynomials
(quadratic, cubic,
quartic) No No No Yes No
Observations 298 298 298 298 298
Log pseudolikelihood �1,570.21 �1,570.07 �1,547.69
�1,567.56 �1,570.07
Note.—Negative binomial regressions. White robust standard
errors are in parentheses. Disturbance terms are clus-
tered by country (there are two observations per country: pre-
enforcement and postenforcement). The omitted region
category is North America/Caribbean.
* Statistically significantly different from zero at 90 percent
confidence.
** Statistically significantly different from zero at 95 percent
confidence.
*** Statistically significantly different from zero at 99 percent
confidence.
This content downloaded from 164.107.70.42 on Wed, 25 Mar
2015 17:53:25 PM
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp
q
Highlight
q
Highlight
q
Highlight
1038 journal of political economy
Fig. 2.—Country corruption and unpaid New York City parking
violations per diplomat
(in logs), pre-enforcement (November 1997 to November 2002).
Country abbreviations
are presented in table 1. The line is the quadratic regression fit.
The y-axis is log(1 �
Annual NYC Parking Violations/Diplomat).
city blocks (roughly one-quarter mile) away from the UN
complex,
where most of the missions are centered. We find that a similar
rela-
tionship between the country corruption and legal enforcement
terms
also holds for this subset of violations (table 4, regression 4).14
The strong relationship between the parking violation
corruption
measure and the country corruption index is robust to different
func-
tional forms. It also holds if the dependent variable is log(1 �
Unpaid
Parking Violations) across specifications (table 4, regression 5)
and is
14 The results in tables 3 and 4 are nearly identical if distance
from the country’s UN
mission to the UN Plaza is included as an additional
explanatory variable (results not
shown). We also examined the most socially egregious New
York City parking violations.
While impoverished diplomats from poor countries might be
forced to park illegally in
order to avoid the extra expense of renting a parking spot, they
could still try to do so
in a manner that avoids excessive negative social externalities.
As indications of “extreme”
violations, we considered (i) parking in front of a fire hydrant
and (ii) violations for
double-parking on east-west streets between Tenth and 100th
streets in Manhattan, rela-
tively narrow streets where double-parking can completely
block passage. The main results
hold robustly for both types of violations (not shown); in other
words, diplomats from
high-corruption countries are much more likely to commit the
most egregious violations.
Hence our results are not driven solely by behaviors causing
minimal social harm (i.e.,
an expired meter in a legal parking spot) or those in which it
may be unclear to the
diplomat that he or she is generating negative externalities.
This content downloaded from 164.107.70.42 on Wed, 25 Mar
2015 17:53:25 PM
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp
q
Highlight
corruption, norms, and legal enforcement 1039
Fig. 3.—Country corruption and unpaid New York City parking
violations per diplomat
(in logs), postenforcement (November 2002 to November 2005).
Country abbreviations
are presented in table 1. The line is the quadratic regression fit.
The y-axis is log(1 �
Annual NYC Parking Violations/Diplomat).
similar for an ordinary least squares (OLS) specification with
unpaid
violations as the dependent variable (regression 6).
Several measures of “proximity” to the United States are
correlated
with fewer unpaid parking violations. First, the log of the
weighted
average distance between a country’s population and the U.S.
popula-
tion15 is strongly positively correlated with parking violations
(table 4,
regression 7), indicating that diplomats from countries in closer
geo-
graphic proximity to the United States have many fewer New
York City
violations. We do not have a definitive explanation for this
pattern;
however, we note that it is not driven by trade volumes, which
are not
a statistically significant predictor of parking violations
(coefficient es-
timate 0.04, standard error 0.07). Migration, tourism, and some
broader
cultural affinity between the countries are other possible
explanations.
Countries that receive U.S. economic aid are significantly less
likely to
commit diplomatic parking violations (with a large effect of 65
log
15 Distance from the United States is taken from Mayer and
Zignago (2005). Their
measure uses city-level data to assess the geographic
distribution of population inside each
nation and calculates the distance between two countries on the
basis of bilateral distances
between the largest cities of those two countries, those intercity
distances being weighted
by the share of the city in the overall country’s population.
This content downloaded from 164.107.70.42 on Wed, 25 Mar
2015 17:53:25 PM
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp
q
Highlight
q
Highlight
1040
T
A
B
L
E
4
C
o
u
n
tr
y
C
h
ar
ac
te
ri
st
ic
s
an
d
U
n
pa
id
N
ew
Yo
rk
C
it
y
Pa
rk
in
g
V
io
la
ti
o
n
s,
N
o
ve
m
be
r
19
97
to
N
o
ve
m
be
r
20
05
:
Se
n
si
ti
vi
ty
Te
st
s
D
ep
en
d
en
t
Va
ri
ab
le
U
n
pa
id
Pa
rk
in
g
V
io
la
ti
on
s
N
eg
at
iv
e
B
in
om
ia
l
(1
)
U
n
pa
id
Pa
rk
in
g
V
io
la
ti
on
s
N
eg
at
iv
e
B
in
om
ia
l
(2
)
Pa
id
an
d
U
n
pa
id
Pa
rk
in
g
V
io
la
ti
on
s
N
eg
at
iv
e
B
in
om
ia
l
(3
)
A
ft
er
-H
ou
rs
Pa
rk
in
g
V
io
la
ti
on
s
N
eg
at
iv
e
B
in
om
ia
l
(4
)
L
og
(1
�
U
n
pa
id
Pa
rk
in
g
V
io
la
ti
on
s)
O
L
S
(5
)
U
n
pa
id
Pa
rk
in
g
V
io
la
ti
on
s
O
L
S
(6
)
U
n
pa
id
Pa
rk
in
g
V
io
la
ti
on
s
N
eg
at
iv
e
B
in
om
ia
l
(7
)
C
ou
n
tr
y
co
rr
up
ti
on
in
de
x,
19
98
1.
01
**
*
.4
8*
*
.4
7*
*
.5
6*
.3
7*
*
12
3.
9*
.7
4*
**
(.
32
)
(.
24
)
(.
18
)
(.
30
)
(.
16
)
(7
2.
3)
(.
23
)
Po
st
en
fo
rc
em
en
t
pe
ri
od
in
di
ca
to
r
(p
os
t-1
1/
20
02
)
�
4.
06
**
*
�
4.
31
**
*
�
3.
36
**
*
�
3.
52
**
*
�
2.
69
**
*
�
96
6.
6*
**
�
4.
34
**
*
(.
15
)
(.
19
)
(.
16
)
(.
21
)
(.
14
)
(1
64
.6
)
(.
19
)
D
ip
lo
m
at
s
.0
6*
*
.0
1
.0
5*
**
.0
4*
21
.1
*
.0
5
(.
03
)
(.
02
)
(.
02
)
(.
02
)
(1
1.
2)
(.
03
)
L
og
pe
r
ca
pi
ta
in
co
m
e
(1
99
8
U
S$
)
.3
2
.0
1
.0
6
�
.0
2
�
.2
4*
*
�
40
.0
.0
2
(.
20
)
(.
14
)
(.
13
)
(.
17
)
(.
10
)
(6
8.
4)
(.
17
)
A
ve
ra
ge
go
ve
rn
m
en
t
w
ag
e/
co
un
tr
y
pe
r
ca
pi
ta
in
co
m
e
.1
5*
*
(.
06
)
This content downloaded from 164.107.70.42 on Wed, 25 Mar
2015 17:53:25 PM
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp
1041
D
ip
lo
m
at
ic
ve
h
ic
le
s
.0
5*
(.
02
)
L
og
di
pl
om
at
s
.7
5*
**
(.
15
)
L
og
w
ei
gh
te
d
di
st
an
ce
of
po
pu
la
ti
on
fr
om
U
n
it
ed
St
at
es
1.
23
**
*
(.
30
)
L
og
to
ta
l
tr
ad
e
w
it
h
th
e
U
n
it
ed
St
at
es
.0
4
(.
07
)
R
ec
ei
ve
d
U
.S
.
ec
on
om
ic
ai
d
�
.6
5*
*
(.
30
)
R
ec
ei
ve
d
U
.S
.
m
ili
ta
ry
ai
d
.1
0
(.
23
)
O
bs
er
va
ti
on
s
18
4
27
8
29
8
29
8
29
8
29
8
28
8
L
og
ps
eu
do
lik
el
ih
oo
d
�
96
7.
23
�
1,
46
3.
60
�
1,
81
6.
45
�
83
1.
14
.
.
.
.
.
.
�
1,
51
0.
79
2
R
.
.
.
.
.
.
.
.
.
.
.
.
.5
2
.1
3
.
.
.
N
o
te
.—
W
h
it
e
ro
bu
st
st
an
da
rd
er
ro
rs
ar
e
in
pa
re
n
th
es
es
.
D
is
tu
rb
an
ce
s
ar
e
cl
us
te
re
d
by
co
un
tr
y.
*
St
at
is
ti
ca
lly
si
gn
ifi
ca
n
tl
y
di
ff
er
en
t
fr
om
ze
ro
at
90
pe
rc
en
t
co
n
fi
de
n
ce
.
**
St
at
is
ti
ca
lly
si
gn
ifi
ca
n
tl
y
di
ff
er
en
t
fr
om
ze
ro
at
95
pe
rc
en
t
co
n
fi
de
n
ce
.
**
*
St
at
is
ti
ca
lly
si
gn
ifi
ca
n
tl
y
di
ff
er
en
t
fr
om
ze
ro
at
99
pe
rc
en
t
co
n
fi
de
n
ce
.
This content downloaded from 164.107.70.42 on Wed, 25 Mar
2015 17:53:25 PM
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp
1042 journal of political economy
points), suggesting that the goodwill engendered by these ties
may help
to limit abuse of diplomatic privileges in New York and
pointing to the
broader role of sentiment in driving norm compliance.16
Since we can follow individual diplomats during their tenure at
the
United Nations, we examine the related question of how
diplomat be-
havior evolves while in New York City. Conceptually, the
relative plau-
sibility of socialization to U.S. norms versus convergence to a
uniform
high-corruption norm is unclear. If convergence is to U.S.
corruption
norms, individuals from high-corruption countries (e.g.,
Nigeria) should
have declining parking violations over time, but there should be
no
change in behavior for diplomats from the low-corruption
societies (e.g.,
Norway). Alternatively, individuals may begin their stay in New
York City
unsure as to the extent to which they can get away with
violations. Once
they successfully “got away with it” a few times (or heard
stories about
others doing so), diplomats may become bolder in their
violations. Thus
convergence to this zero-enforcement norm predicts increasing
viola-
tions over time, particularly among diplomats from less corrupt
countries.
In practice, to estimate these effects, we use a negative
binomial re-
gression like that discussed above, but with observations at the
diplomat-
month level of analysis. We include month-year fixed effects (
). Theat
two key explanatory variables are the effect of increased time
spent
working as a consular official in New York City on parking
violations
and the differential time effect for diplomats from countries
with higher
corruption (the interaction effect of time spent working in New
York
City with the country corruption index). Disturbance terms are
allowed
to be correlated across the monthly observations for the same
individual.
The parking violations included in the individual-level analysis
are a
subset of those used at the country level: violations committed
using
official consular vehicles are excluded below since they cannot
be
matched to any one diplomat.
The frequency of unpaid violations increases rapidly and
statistically
significantly with tenure in New York City (table 5, regression
1), seem-
ingly ruling out convergence to the U.S. norm of rule
adherence. On
average, parking violations increase by 8.4 percent with each
additional
16 An additional direct measure of affinity is provided by the
Pew Global Attitudes Survey
from 2002 (the earliest year that the survey was performed),
based on responses to the
question “Please tell me if you have a very favorable, somewhat
favorable, somewhat un-
favorable, or very unfavorable opinion of the United States.”
This is coded to take on
values from one (most favorable) to four (least favorable) and
then averaged across re-
spondents. In some specifications, the anti-U.S. sentiment term
is a large and statistically
significant predictor of more parking violations (see Fisman and
Miguel 2006). However,
the result does not robustly hold when the negative binomial
specification is used, and
thus we do not emphasize it. A main limitation of the analysis
with the Pew data is the
small sample of only 42 countries. The data are available at
http://pewglobal.org/.
This content downloaded from 164.107.70.42 on Wed, 25 Mar
2015 17:53:25 PM
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp
q
Highlight
q
Highlight
q
Highlight
q
Highlight
q
Highlight
q
Highlight
q
Highlight
q
Highlight
corruption, norms, and legal enforcement 1043
TABLE 5
Unpaid Parking Violations at the Diplomat level, November
1997 to
November 2005
Dependent Variable:
Unpaid Parking Viola-
tions (Monthly)
Negative
Binomial
(1)
Negative
Binomial
(2)
Country corruption index, 1998 .150 .390***
(.120) (.117)
Log length of time in New York City (in
months) .084*** .090***
(.005) (.006)
Log length of time in New York City # coun-
try corruption index �.027***
(.006)
Month fixed effects Yes Yes
Observations (diplomats) 40,929
(5,338)
40,929
(5,338)
Log pseudolikelihood �23,733 �23,621
Note.—White robust standard errors are in parentheses.
Disturbance terms are clustered by country. Observations
are at the diplomat-month level. Month fixed effects are
included in all regressions (thus the postenforcement
indicator is not included). The log per capita income (1998
US$) term is included as a control in cols. 1–2 (results
not shown).
* Statistically significantly different from zero at 90 percent
confidence.
** Statistically significantly different from zero at 95 percent
confidence.
*** Statistically significantly different from zero at 99 percent
confidence.
month a diplomat lives in New York, perhaps as he or she learns
about
the reality of diplomatic immunity. Diplomats from low-
corruption coun-
tries show the most rapid proportional increases in violations
over time
(regression 2), consistent with partial convergence to the zero-
enforce-
ment norm, although the large proportional increases among
diplomats
from low-corruption countries are from a much lower base rate
of vi-
olations. This increase in parking violations among those from
low-
corruption countries occurs almost entirely in the pre-
enforcement pe-
riod (result not shown), an indication that their attachment to
home
country anticorruption norms was partly eroded by time spent in
New
York City’s lawless pre–November 2002 parking
environment.17
Alternative explanations.—Informal or formal social sanctions
against
diplomats in the home country could be partially responsible for
re-
straining parking violations through, for example, public
embarrass-
ment in the media upon returning home or punishment by the
dip-
17 Similar results hold with alternative specifications, including
a linear regression model
(not shown). When diplomat fixed effects are included in a
linear model, the coefficient
estimate on the interaction between months in New York City
and country corruption is
negative but no longer statistically significant. Results are
virtually identical if individuals
who arrived only after the earliest UN Blue Book was published
are excluded, which allows
us to more accurately capture tenure in New York City (not
shown).
This content downloaded from 164.107.70.42 on Wed, 25 Mar
2015 17:53:25 PM
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp
q
Highlight
1044 journal of political economy
lomatic service. If the potential response of others in the home
country,
either informally or formally, is responsible for limiting parking
viola-
tions, then diplomats’ behaviors are better interpreted as an
indication
of their home country’s cultural tolerance for corruption rather
than
their own personal values. However, this is still consistent with
the basic
interpretation of the level of New York City parking violations
as a re-
vealed preference measure of country corruption norms in the
absence
of formal legal enforcement. In such cases, diplomats’
behaviors are
better interpreted as an indication of their home country’s
norms or
culture rather than their own personal values.
Several findings argue somewhat against this interpretation that
non-
legal punishments such as media embarrassment or workplace
punish-
ment are the main drivers of our findings. First, a Lexis-Nexis
search
of 504 European news outlets (English language or in
translation) using
the terms “diplomats” and “parking” and “New York” yielded
only 25
stories during the entire study period, and these stories were
concen-
trated in just four countries (the United Kingdom, Germany,
France,
and Russia). Further, with the exception of several Russian
articles, the
stories were about the general problem of diplomatic parking
violations
in New York City and the 2002 crackdown rather than reporting
on the
behavior of home country diplomats. The possibility of
sanctions for
returning diplomats who accumulated parking tickets while
abroad is
apparently not a leading media issue, in Europe at least.
Second, we considered whether unpaid parking violations early
in an
official’s tenure at the United Nations in New York City are
correlated
with the length of his employment there, and further whether
these
early violations interact in any way with corruption in the
country of
origin (i.e., perhaps violators from low-corruption countries
could be
punished by their government and sent home early). We find no
evi-
dence for any such effects of parking violations on diplomat
tenure
(regressions not shown).
Obviously, neither of these two findings is completely
conclusive in
terms of pinning down the exact channel for the culture results.
In
equilibrium the number of violations committed could reflect
choices
made, in part, to avoid home country sanctions. But they are
certainly
consistent with the widely held view among New York City
officials that
home country enforcement is typically weak or nonexistent.18
A related
concern is that public pressure could have a larger effect on
diplomats’
choices in a more democratic political setting. However, we do
not find
that the number of parking violations is statistically
significantly related
18 Gillian Sorensen, former New York City Commissioner for
the United Nations and
Consular Affairs in the 1980s, claims that during her tenure UN
missions in New York
City rarely, if ever, punished their employees for parking
tickets, even in the most egregious
cases (personal communication, February 8, 2007).
This content downloaded from 164.107.70.42 on Wed, 25 Mar
2015 17:53:25 PM
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp
corruption, norms, and legal enforcement 1045
to democracy (as measured by the Polity IV democracy scale in
1998),
nor is the coefficient on corruption affected at all by its
inclusion (re-
gressions not shown).19
V. Conclusion
We exploit a unique natural experiment—the stationing in New
York
City of thousands of government officials from 149 countries
around
the world—in a setting of zero legal enforcement of parking
violations
to construct a revealed preference measure of official
corruption, and
then estimate how behavior changes when legal enforcement
increased.
We find that the number of diplomatic parking violations is
strongly
correlated with existing measures of home country corruption.
This
finding suggests that cultural or social norms related to
corruption are
quite persistent: even when stationed thousands of miles away,
diplomats
behave in a manner highly reminiscent of government officials
in the
home country. Norms related to corruption are apparently
deeply in-
grained, and factors other than legal enforcement are important
de-
terminants of corruption behavior. Nonetheless, increased legal
en-
forcement is also highly influential: parking violations fell by
over 98
percent after enforcement was introduced. New York City is an
attractive
location to study increased enforcement relative to many less
developed
countries, where official changes “on the books” may not
always translate
into greater actual enforcement on the ground.
The result on sticky corruption cultures raises the critical
question of
whether there are policy interventions that can modify
corruption norms
over time. For example, the Bloomberg administration’s
enforcement
efforts in New York City in 2002 were extremely successful in
changing
diplomats’ behaviors, and it would be useful to know whether
these
changes might additionally have had persistent effects on norms
once
individuals become habituated to rule-compliant behavior. Such
long-
run effects of temporary interventions necessarily rely on a shift
in norms
(or tastes) and would be consistent with the findings of Di Tella
and
Schargrodsky (2003) on the persistent effects of auditing on
corruption
19 A final consideration is whether there is a differential
selection mechanism for UN
diplomats across countries that might account for the pattern we
observe. In particular,
it would be problematic if the relatively more corrupt
government officials (within the
distribution of officials in a country) were selected for New
York postings from high-
corruption countries. We have no rigorous statistical test to
explore this possibility, but
we feel that it is unlikely to be of first-order importance for
several reasons. First, UN
mission staff are selected along a range of common
characteristics, including English
language skills, education, and diplomatic experience, and this
reduces the gap between
diplomats in terms of their personal attributes. Further, we are
not concerned with dif-
ferential selection of “corrupt” types into the government
bureaucracy vs. the private sector
across countries, since we are interested in the behavior of
actual government civil servants,
such as the UN mission diplomats we observe.
This content downloaded from 164.107.70.42 on Wed, 25 Mar
2015 17:53:25 PM
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp
1046 journal of political economy
in Argentina. Unfortunately, our context does not accommodate
this
analysis. Understanding better how corruption norms evolve is
likely to
be critical for the success of anticorruption reforms such as
those cur-
rently widely advocated by the World Bank and other foreign
aid donors.
Data Appendix
A. New York City Diplomatic Parking Violation Data
The New York City Department of Finance supplied listings of
all unpaid parking
violations of UN missions. The violations covered the period
from November
24, 1997, to November 21, 2005. In order to appear in the
database, a violation
had to go unpaid for at least 100 days. Data were at the level of
the violation
and included the following entries for each violation:
• Summons: unique identification number for the violation
• License plate number of the violating car
• The person to whom the violating car was registered, often the
mission
itself
• Time of violation: included both hour and minute as well as
calendar date
• Type of violation, e.g., expired meter, fire hydrant
• Street address of violation
• Initial dollar value of fine issued
• Additional dollar penalty for not having paid the fine on time
• Amount paid toward the fine, generally zero
• Name of country to which the car is registered
Data on UN diplomats’ paid parking violations (violations that
did not go
into arrears) were made available to us in aggregate form by the
New York City
Department of Finance.
B. UN Blue Books
The United Nations issues its list of mission personnel, or Blue
Book, twice
yearly. We utilize edition numbers 278 (January 1997) through
294 (October
2005). Documents were retrieved from the UN Official
Document System, avail-
able at http://documents.un.org/advance.asp. Searching for the
symbol ST/
SG/SER.A/### with truncation turned off returns the relevant
Blue Book (where
### is the Blue Book edition number). Edition 280 (May 1998)
was checked by
hand to count the mission staff and spouses for each country in
the Blue Book,
producing the following variables:
• Mission: indicator variable indicating whether the country had
a UN
mission
• Staff: simple count of staff (staff members are always listed
with their sur-
names in bold)
To create the longitudinal data set of diplomat parking
violations, the Blue
Book data were first converted into filtered html format. A
program was used
to parse the name and country of each diplomat in each Blue
Book. Next,
diplomat names from the Blue Books were matched to the
parking violation
data. A name was considered to have “matched” if the country,
last name, and
first four letters of the first name corresponded across data sets.
There was some
This content downloaded from 164.107.70.42 on Wed, 25 Mar
2015 17:53:25 PM
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp
corruption, norms, and legal enforcement 1047
manual double-checking of apparent spelling typos and
duplicate or otherwise
confusing names. Diplomats are considered “present” in New
York City in the
analysis for the months after their first appearance in a Blue
Book and before
the first Blue Book in which they no longer appear. Since Blue
Books are pro-
duced only sporadically, in months between a final Blue Book
appearance and
the first “nonappearance,” we assume arbitrarily that diplomats
left New York
at the midpoint in time between these months.
C. Diplomatic Vehicles
Data were provided by Murray Smith, Deputy Director at the
U.S. State De-
partment’s Office of Foreign Missions in April 2006. These data
report counts
of the number of vehicles with diplomatic license plates
registered to each
mission in early 2006.
References
Agence France–Presse. 2005. “Speedy Diplomats Steer Clear of
Fines in France.”
March 16.
BBC News. 1998. “So What Are Diplomats Immune To?”
October 28. http://
news.bbc.co.uk/1/hi/special_report/1998/10/98/e-
cyclopedia/196677.stm.
Becker, Gary S. 1968. “Crime and Punishment: An Economic
Approach.” J.P.E.
76 (March/April): 169–217.
Borjas, George J. 2000. “The Economic Progress of
Immigrants.” In Issues in the
Economics of Immigration, edited by George J. Borjas.
Chicago: Univ. Chicago
Press (for NBER).
Di Tella, Rafael, and Ernesto Schargrodsky. 2003. “The Role of
Wages and Au-
diting during a Crackdown on Corruption in the City of Buenos
Aires.” J.
Law and Econ. 46 (April): 269–92.
Fernandez, Raquel, and Alessandra Fogli. 2006. “Fertility: The
Role of Culture
and Family Experience.” J. European Econ. Assoc. 4 (April–
May): 552–61.
Fisman, Raymond, and Edward Miguel. 2006. “Cultures of
Corruption: Evidence
from Diplomatic Parking Tickets.” Working Paper no. 12312
(June), NBER,
Cambridge, MA.
Fries, Jacob H. 2002. “U.S. Revokes License Plates Issued to
185 at 30 Consulates.”
New York Times, September 7.
Ichino, Andrea, and Giovanni Maggi. 2000. “Work Environment
and Individual
Background: Explaining Regional Shirking Differentials in a
Large Italian
Firm.” Q.J.E. 115 (August): 1057–90.
Kaufmann, Daniel, Aart Kraay, and Massimo Mastruzzi. 2005.
“Governance Mat-
ters IV: Governance Indicators for 1996–2004.” Policy Research
Working Paper
no. 3630, World Bank, Washington, DC.
Korea Times. 1999. “Illegal Parking by Diplomats on Rise.”
November 1.
Kuziemko, Ilyana, and Eric Werker. 2006. “How Much Is a Seat
on the Security
Council Worth? Foreign Aid and Bribery at the United
Nations.” J.P.E. 114
(October): 905–30.
Lambsdorff, Johann Graf. 2006. “Causes and Consequences of
Corruption: What
Do We Know from a Cross-Section of Countries?” In
International Handbook
on the Economics of Corruption, edited by Susan Rose-
Ackerman. Northampton,
MA: Elgar.
Ledyard, John O. 1995. “Public Goods: A Survey of
Experimental Research.” In
This content downloaded from 164.107.70.42 on Wed, 25 Mar
2015 17:53:25 PM
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp
1048 journal of political economy
The Handbook of Experimental Economics, edited by John H.
Kagel and Alvin E.
Roth. Princeton, NJ: Princeton Univ. Press.
Levitt, Steven D. 1997. “Using Electoral Cycles in Police
Hiring to Estimate the
Effect of Police on Crime.” A.E.R. 87 (June): 270–90.
———. 2004. “Understanding Why Crime Fell in the 1990s:
Four Factors That
Explain the Decline and Six That Do Not.” J. Econ.
Perspectives 18 (Winter):
163–90.
———. 2006. “An Economist Sells Bagels: A Case Study in
Profit Maximization.”
Working Paper no. 12152 (April), NBER, Cambridge, MA.
Mauro, Paolo. 2004. “The Persistence of Corruption and Slow
Economic
Growth.” IMF Staff Papers 51 (1): 1–18.
Mayer, Thierry, and Soledad Zignago. 2005. “Market Access in
Global and Re-
gional Trade.” Working Paper no. 2005-02 (January), Centre
d’Etudes Pros-
pectives et d’Informations Internationales, Paris.
Olken, Benjamin A. 2006. “Corruption Perceptions vs.
Corruption Reality.” Man-
uscript, Harvard Univ.
Reinikka, Ritva, and Jakob Svensson. 2004. “Local Capture:
Evidence from a
Central Government Transfer Program in Uganda.” Q.J.E. 119
(May): 679–
705.
Rockwell, John. 2004. “Reverberations: Where Mimes Patrolled
the Streets and
the Mayor Was Superman.” New York Times, July 9.
Schiavo-Campo, Salvatore, Giulio de Tommaso, and Amit
Mukherjee. 1999. “An
International Statistical Survey of Government Employment and
Wages.” Pol-
icy Research Working Paper no. 1806, World Bank,
Washington, DC.
Singleton, Don. 2004. “Bill Socks Scofflaw Diplos.” New York
Daily News, November
21, p. 28.
Steinhauer, Jennifer. 2002. “Suspension of Hostilities over
Diplomats’ Tickets.”
New York Times, August 23.
Tirole, Jean. 1996. “A Theory of Collective Reputations (with
Applications to
the Persistence of Corruption and to Firm Quality).” Rev. Econ.
Studies 63
(January): 1–22.
Witzel, Morgen. 2005. “How to Respond When Only Bribe
Money Talks.” Fi-
nancial Times, July 11, London ed. 1, p. 14.
This content downloaded from 164.107.70.42 on Wed, 25 Mar
2015 17:53:25 PM
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp

More Related Content

Similar to Corruption, Norms, and Legal Enforcement Evidence from Diplom.docx

Corruption, Judicial Accountability and Inequality: Unfair Procedures May Ben...
Corruption, Judicial Accountability and Inequality: Unfair Procedures May Ben...Corruption, Judicial Accountability and Inequality: Unfair Procedures May Ben...
Corruption, Judicial Accountability and Inequality: Unfair Procedures May Ben...Stockholm Institute of Transition Economics
 
Dr.sc.Mensut Ademi The role of police reducing the fear of crimePresentation....
Dr.sc.Mensut Ademi The role of police reducing the fear of crimePresentation....Dr.sc.Mensut Ademi The role of police reducing the fear of crimePresentation....
Dr.sc.Mensut Ademi The role of police reducing the fear of crimePresentation....AdeaAdemi1
 
PROTECTING THE NATION’S CYBER SYSTEMS 9WHAT ARE THE .docx
PROTECTING THE NATION’S CYBER SYSTEMS    9WHAT ARE THE .docxPROTECTING THE NATION’S CYBER SYSTEMS    9WHAT ARE THE .docx
PROTECTING THE NATION’S CYBER SYSTEMS 9WHAT ARE THE .docxbriancrawford30935
 
Present cumbre OGP sna_omgf_291115 (english)
Present cumbre OGP sna_omgf_291115 (english)Present cumbre OGP sna_omgf_291115 (english)
Present cumbre OGP sna_omgf_291115 (english)Ernesto Iturbe
 
E-Government and Social Media as openess and anti-corruption tools
E-Government and Social Media as openess and anti-corruption toolsE-Government and Social Media as openess and anti-corruption tools
E-Government and Social Media as openess and anti-corruption toolsDr Lendy Spires
 
Cryptocurrency enforcement framework - Report by the U.S. Department of Justice
Cryptocurrency enforcement framework - Report by the U.S. Department of JusticeCryptocurrency enforcement framework - Report by the U.S. Department of Justice
Cryptocurrency enforcement framework - Report by the U.S. Department of JusticeLoeb Smith Attorneys
 
An evaluation of_governance_indicators
An evaluation of_governance_indicatorsAn evaluation of_governance_indicators
An evaluation of_governance_indicatorsMalik Khalid Mehmood
 
Organizational Sign-on Letter Final 7.19.14
Organizational Sign-on Letter Final 7.19.14Organizational Sign-on Letter Final 7.19.14
Organizational Sign-on Letter Final 7.19.14Kyle Graczyk
 
MCJ 6530, Critical Analysis of Criminal Justice Public.docx
  MCJ 6530, Critical Analysis of Criminal Justice Public.docx  MCJ 6530, Critical Analysis of Criminal Justice Public.docx
MCJ 6530, Critical Analysis of Criminal Justice Public.docxShiraPrater50
 
MCJ 6530, Critical Analysis of Criminal Justice Public.docx
MCJ 6530, Critical Analysis of Criminal Justice Public.docxMCJ 6530, Critical Analysis of Criminal Justice Public.docx
MCJ 6530, Critical Analysis of Criminal Justice Public.docxadkinspaige22
 
Factors Influencing Adherence to Ethical Values: A Case Study of Accountants ...
Factors Influencing Adherence to Ethical Values: A Case Study of Accountants ...Factors Influencing Adherence to Ethical Values: A Case Study of Accountants ...
Factors Influencing Adherence to Ethical Values: A Case Study of Accountants ...VandanaSharma356
 
239 325 ethics
239 325 ethics239 325 ethics
239 325 ethicssyed ahmed
 
Running head NEIGHBORHOOD WATCH1NEIGHBORHOOD WATCH.docx
Running head NEIGHBORHOOD WATCH1NEIGHBORHOOD WATCH.docxRunning head NEIGHBORHOOD WATCH1NEIGHBORHOOD WATCH.docx
Running head NEIGHBORHOOD WATCH1NEIGHBORHOOD WATCH.docxtoltonkendal
 
Dr haluk f gursel, keeping tax supported officials around the globe accountable
Dr haluk f gursel, keeping tax supported officials around the globe accountableDr haluk f gursel, keeping tax supported officials around the globe accountable
Dr haluk f gursel, keeping tax supported officials around the globe accountableHaluk Ferden Gursel
 
Dr haluk f gursel, keeping tax supported officials around the globe accountable
Dr haluk f gursel, keeping tax supported officials around the globe accountableDr haluk f gursel, keeping tax supported officials around the globe accountable
Dr haluk f gursel, keeping tax supported officials around the globe accountableHaluk Ferden Gursel
 
Social Media Intelligence
Social Media IntelligenceSocial Media Intelligence
Social Media IntelligenceTwittercrisis
 

Similar to Corruption, Norms, and Legal Enforcement Evidence from Diplom.docx (20)

Corruption, Judicial Accountability and Inequality: Unfair Procedures May Ben...
Corruption, Judicial Accountability and Inequality: Unfair Procedures May Ben...Corruption, Judicial Accountability and Inequality: Unfair Procedures May Ben...
Corruption, Judicial Accountability and Inequality: Unfair Procedures May Ben...
 
MASTERS ESSAY FINAL
MASTERS ESSAY FINALMASTERS ESSAY FINAL
MASTERS ESSAY FINAL
 
Dr.sc.Mensut Ademi The role of police reducing the fear of crimePresentation....
Dr.sc.Mensut Ademi The role of police reducing the fear of crimePresentation....Dr.sc.Mensut Ademi The role of police reducing the fear of crimePresentation....
Dr.sc.Mensut Ademi The role of police reducing the fear of crimePresentation....
 
PROTECTING THE NATION’S CYBER SYSTEMS 9WHAT ARE THE .docx
PROTECTING THE NATION’S CYBER SYSTEMS    9WHAT ARE THE .docxPROTECTING THE NATION’S CYBER SYSTEMS    9WHAT ARE THE .docx
PROTECTING THE NATION’S CYBER SYSTEMS 9WHAT ARE THE .docx
 
Present cumbre OGP sna_omgf_291115 (english)
Present cumbre OGP sna_omgf_291115 (english)Present cumbre OGP sna_omgf_291115 (english)
Present cumbre OGP sna_omgf_291115 (english)
 
Trust, Salience and Deterrence
Trust, Salience and DeterrenceTrust, Salience and Deterrence
Trust, Salience and Deterrence
 
E-Government and Social Media as openess and anti-corruption tools
E-Government and Social Media as openess and anti-corruption toolsE-Government and Social Media as openess and anti-corruption tools
E-Government and Social Media as openess and anti-corruption tools
 
Cryptocurrency enforcement framework - Report by the U.S. Department of Justice
Cryptocurrency enforcement framework - Report by the U.S. Department of JusticeCryptocurrency enforcement framework - Report by the U.S. Department of Justice
Cryptocurrency enforcement framework - Report by the U.S. Department of Justice
 
An evaluation of_governance_indicators
An evaluation of_governance_indicatorsAn evaluation of_governance_indicators
An evaluation of_governance_indicators
 
Organizational Sign-on Letter Final 7.19.14
Organizational Sign-on Letter Final 7.19.14Organizational Sign-on Letter Final 7.19.14
Organizational Sign-on Letter Final 7.19.14
 
MCJ 6530, Critical Analysis of Criminal Justice Public.docx
  MCJ 6530, Critical Analysis of Criminal Justice Public.docx  MCJ 6530, Critical Analysis of Criminal Justice Public.docx
MCJ 6530, Critical Analysis of Criminal Justice Public.docx
 
MCJ 6530, Critical Analysis of Criminal Justice Public.docx
MCJ 6530, Critical Analysis of Criminal Justice Public.docxMCJ 6530, Critical Analysis of Criminal Justice Public.docx
MCJ 6530, Critical Analysis of Criminal Justice Public.docx
 
Marcelin mathur irfa 2014
Marcelin mathur irfa 2014Marcelin mathur irfa 2014
Marcelin mathur irfa 2014
 
Leniency, Asymmetric Punishment and Corruption Evidence from China
Leniency, Asymmetric Punishment and Corruption Evidence from ChinaLeniency, Asymmetric Punishment and Corruption Evidence from China
Leniency, Asymmetric Punishment and Corruption Evidence from China
 
Factors Influencing Adherence to Ethical Values: A Case Study of Accountants ...
Factors Influencing Adherence to Ethical Values: A Case Study of Accountants ...Factors Influencing Adherence to Ethical Values: A Case Study of Accountants ...
Factors Influencing Adherence to Ethical Values: A Case Study of Accountants ...
 
239 325 ethics
239 325 ethics239 325 ethics
239 325 ethics
 
Running head NEIGHBORHOOD WATCH1NEIGHBORHOOD WATCH.docx
Running head NEIGHBORHOOD WATCH1NEIGHBORHOOD WATCH.docxRunning head NEIGHBORHOOD WATCH1NEIGHBORHOOD WATCH.docx
Running head NEIGHBORHOOD WATCH1NEIGHBORHOOD WATCH.docx
 
Dr haluk f gursel, keeping tax supported officials around the globe accountable
Dr haluk f gursel, keeping tax supported officials around the globe accountableDr haluk f gursel, keeping tax supported officials around the globe accountable
Dr haluk f gursel, keeping tax supported officials around the globe accountable
 
Dr haluk f gursel, keeping tax supported officials around the globe accountable
Dr haluk f gursel, keeping tax supported officials around the globe accountableDr haluk f gursel, keeping tax supported officials around the globe accountable
Dr haluk f gursel, keeping tax supported officials around the globe accountable
 
Social Media Intelligence
Social Media IntelligenceSocial Media Intelligence
Social Media Intelligence
 

More from richardnorman90310

BUSI 520Discussion Board Forum InstructionsThreadMarket.docx
BUSI 520Discussion Board Forum InstructionsThreadMarket.docxBUSI 520Discussion Board Forum InstructionsThreadMarket.docx
BUSI 520Discussion Board Forum InstructionsThreadMarket.docxrichardnorman90310
 
BUSI 330Collaborative Marketing Plan Final Draft Instructions.docx
BUSI 330Collaborative Marketing Plan Final Draft Instructions.docxBUSI 330Collaborative Marketing Plan Final Draft Instructions.docx
BUSI 330Collaborative Marketing Plan Final Draft Instructions.docxrichardnorman90310
 
BUSI 460 – LT Assignment Brief 1 ACADEMIC YEAR 2020 – S.docx
BUSI 460 – LT Assignment Brief 1 ACADEMIC YEAR  2020 – S.docxBUSI 460 – LT Assignment Brief 1 ACADEMIC YEAR  2020 – S.docx
BUSI 460 – LT Assignment Brief 1 ACADEMIC YEAR 2020 – S.docxrichardnorman90310
 
BUS475 week#7Diversity in the work environment promotes accept.docx
BUS475 week#7Diversity in the work environment promotes accept.docxBUS475 week#7Diversity in the work environment promotes accept.docx
BUS475 week#7Diversity in the work environment promotes accept.docxrichardnorman90310
 
BUS475week#5In Chapter 11 of your textbook, you explored import.docx
BUS475week#5In Chapter 11 of your textbook, you explored import.docxBUS475week#5In Chapter 11 of your textbook, you explored import.docx
BUS475week#5In Chapter 11 of your textbook, you explored import.docxrichardnorman90310
 
BUS475week#6Share a recent or current event in which a busine.docx
BUS475week#6Share a recent or current event in which a busine.docxBUS475week#6Share a recent or current event in which a busine.docx
BUS475week#6Share a recent or current event in which a busine.docxrichardnorman90310
 
BUS475v10Project PlanBUS475 v10Page 2 of 2Wk 4 – App.docx
BUS475v10Project PlanBUS475 v10Page 2 of 2Wk 4 – App.docxBUS475v10Project PlanBUS475 v10Page 2 of 2Wk 4 – App.docx
BUS475v10Project PlanBUS475 v10Page 2 of 2Wk 4 – App.docxrichardnorman90310
 
BUS472L – Unit 2 & 4 AssignmentStudent Name ___________________.docx
BUS472L – Unit 2 & 4 AssignmentStudent Name ___________________.docxBUS472L – Unit 2 & 4 AssignmentStudent Name ___________________.docx
BUS472L – Unit 2 & 4 AssignmentStudent Name ___________________.docxrichardnorman90310
 
BUS308 Week 4 Lecture 1 Examining Relationships Expect.docx
BUS308 Week 4 Lecture 1 Examining Relationships Expect.docxBUS308 Week 4 Lecture 1 Examining Relationships Expect.docx
BUS308 Week 4 Lecture 1 Examining Relationships Expect.docxrichardnorman90310
 
BUS301 Memo Rubric Spring 2020 - Student.docxBUS301 Writing Ru.docx
BUS301 Memo Rubric Spring 2020 - Student.docxBUS301 Writing Ru.docxBUS301 Memo Rubric Spring 2020 - Student.docxBUS301 Writing Ru.docx
BUS301 Memo Rubric Spring 2020 - Student.docxBUS301 Writing Ru.docxrichardnorman90310
 
BUS 206 Milestone Two Template To simplify completi.docx
BUS 206 Milestone Two Template  To simplify completi.docxBUS 206 Milestone Two Template  To simplify completi.docx
BUS 206 Milestone Two Template To simplify completi.docxrichardnorman90310
 
BurkleyFirst edition Chapter 14Situational InfluencesC.docx
BurkleyFirst edition Chapter 14Situational InfluencesC.docxBurkleyFirst edition Chapter 14Situational InfluencesC.docx
BurkleyFirst edition Chapter 14Situational InfluencesC.docxrichardnorman90310
 
BurkleyFirst edition Chapter 7BelongingCopyright © 201.docx
BurkleyFirst edition Chapter 7BelongingCopyright © 201.docxBurkleyFirst edition Chapter 7BelongingCopyright © 201.docx
BurkleyFirst edition Chapter 7BelongingCopyright © 201.docxrichardnorman90310
 
BurkleyFirst edition Chapter 5AutonomyCopyright © 2018.docx
BurkleyFirst edition Chapter 5AutonomyCopyright © 2018.docxBurkleyFirst edition Chapter 5AutonomyCopyright © 2018.docx
BurkleyFirst edition Chapter 5AutonomyCopyright © 2018.docxrichardnorman90310
 
Bunker Hill Community College MAT 093 Foundations of Mathema.docx
Bunker Hill Community College  MAT 093 Foundations of Mathema.docxBunker Hill Community College  MAT 093 Foundations of Mathema.docx
Bunker Hill Community College MAT 093 Foundations of Mathema.docxrichardnorman90310
 
BurkleyFirst edition Chapter 3Psychological Origins of M.docx
BurkleyFirst edition Chapter 3Psychological Origins of M.docxBurkleyFirst edition Chapter 3Psychological Origins of M.docx
BurkleyFirst edition Chapter 3Psychological Origins of M.docxrichardnorman90310
 
Bullying and cyberbullying of adolescents have become increasingly p.docx
Bullying and cyberbullying of adolescents have become increasingly p.docxBullying and cyberbullying of adolescents have become increasingly p.docx
Bullying and cyberbullying of adolescents have become increasingly p.docxrichardnorman90310
 
Building an Information Technology Security Awareness an.docx
Building an Information Technology Security Awareness an.docxBuilding an Information Technology Security Awareness an.docx
Building an Information Technology Security Awareness an.docxrichardnorman90310
 
Building a company with the help of IT is really necessary as most.docx
Building a company with the help of IT is really necessary as most.docxBuilding a company with the help of IT is really necessary as most.docx
Building a company with the help of IT is really necessary as most.docxrichardnorman90310
 
Building a Comprehensive Health HistoryBuild a health histor.docx
Building a Comprehensive Health HistoryBuild a health histor.docxBuilding a Comprehensive Health HistoryBuild a health histor.docx
Building a Comprehensive Health HistoryBuild a health histor.docxrichardnorman90310
 

More from richardnorman90310 (20)

BUSI 520Discussion Board Forum InstructionsThreadMarket.docx
BUSI 520Discussion Board Forum InstructionsThreadMarket.docxBUSI 520Discussion Board Forum InstructionsThreadMarket.docx
BUSI 520Discussion Board Forum InstructionsThreadMarket.docx
 
BUSI 330Collaborative Marketing Plan Final Draft Instructions.docx
BUSI 330Collaborative Marketing Plan Final Draft Instructions.docxBUSI 330Collaborative Marketing Plan Final Draft Instructions.docx
BUSI 330Collaborative Marketing Plan Final Draft Instructions.docx
 
BUSI 460 – LT Assignment Brief 1 ACADEMIC YEAR 2020 – S.docx
BUSI 460 – LT Assignment Brief 1 ACADEMIC YEAR  2020 – S.docxBUSI 460 – LT Assignment Brief 1 ACADEMIC YEAR  2020 – S.docx
BUSI 460 – LT Assignment Brief 1 ACADEMIC YEAR 2020 – S.docx
 
BUS475 week#7Diversity in the work environment promotes accept.docx
BUS475 week#7Diversity in the work environment promotes accept.docxBUS475 week#7Diversity in the work environment promotes accept.docx
BUS475 week#7Diversity in the work environment promotes accept.docx
 
BUS475week#5In Chapter 11 of your textbook, you explored import.docx
BUS475week#5In Chapter 11 of your textbook, you explored import.docxBUS475week#5In Chapter 11 of your textbook, you explored import.docx
BUS475week#5In Chapter 11 of your textbook, you explored import.docx
 
BUS475week#6Share a recent or current event in which a busine.docx
BUS475week#6Share a recent or current event in which a busine.docxBUS475week#6Share a recent or current event in which a busine.docx
BUS475week#6Share a recent or current event in which a busine.docx
 
BUS475v10Project PlanBUS475 v10Page 2 of 2Wk 4 – App.docx
BUS475v10Project PlanBUS475 v10Page 2 of 2Wk 4 – App.docxBUS475v10Project PlanBUS475 v10Page 2 of 2Wk 4 – App.docx
BUS475v10Project PlanBUS475 v10Page 2 of 2Wk 4 – App.docx
 
BUS472L – Unit 2 & 4 AssignmentStudent Name ___________________.docx
BUS472L – Unit 2 & 4 AssignmentStudent Name ___________________.docxBUS472L – Unit 2 & 4 AssignmentStudent Name ___________________.docx
BUS472L – Unit 2 & 4 AssignmentStudent Name ___________________.docx
 
BUS308 Week 4 Lecture 1 Examining Relationships Expect.docx
BUS308 Week 4 Lecture 1 Examining Relationships Expect.docxBUS308 Week 4 Lecture 1 Examining Relationships Expect.docx
BUS308 Week 4 Lecture 1 Examining Relationships Expect.docx
 
BUS301 Memo Rubric Spring 2020 - Student.docxBUS301 Writing Ru.docx
BUS301 Memo Rubric Spring 2020 - Student.docxBUS301 Writing Ru.docxBUS301 Memo Rubric Spring 2020 - Student.docxBUS301 Writing Ru.docx
BUS301 Memo Rubric Spring 2020 - Student.docxBUS301 Writing Ru.docx
 
BUS 206 Milestone Two Template To simplify completi.docx
BUS 206 Milestone Two Template  To simplify completi.docxBUS 206 Milestone Two Template  To simplify completi.docx
BUS 206 Milestone Two Template To simplify completi.docx
 
BurkleyFirst edition Chapter 14Situational InfluencesC.docx
BurkleyFirst edition Chapter 14Situational InfluencesC.docxBurkleyFirst edition Chapter 14Situational InfluencesC.docx
BurkleyFirst edition Chapter 14Situational InfluencesC.docx
 
BurkleyFirst edition Chapter 7BelongingCopyright © 201.docx
BurkleyFirst edition Chapter 7BelongingCopyright © 201.docxBurkleyFirst edition Chapter 7BelongingCopyright © 201.docx
BurkleyFirst edition Chapter 7BelongingCopyright © 201.docx
 
BurkleyFirst edition Chapter 5AutonomyCopyright © 2018.docx
BurkleyFirst edition Chapter 5AutonomyCopyright © 2018.docxBurkleyFirst edition Chapter 5AutonomyCopyright © 2018.docx
BurkleyFirst edition Chapter 5AutonomyCopyright © 2018.docx
 
Bunker Hill Community College MAT 093 Foundations of Mathema.docx
Bunker Hill Community College  MAT 093 Foundations of Mathema.docxBunker Hill Community College  MAT 093 Foundations of Mathema.docx
Bunker Hill Community College MAT 093 Foundations of Mathema.docx
 
BurkleyFirst edition Chapter 3Psychological Origins of M.docx
BurkleyFirst edition Chapter 3Psychological Origins of M.docxBurkleyFirst edition Chapter 3Psychological Origins of M.docx
BurkleyFirst edition Chapter 3Psychological Origins of M.docx
 
Bullying and cyberbullying of adolescents have become increasingly p.docx
Bullying and cyberbullying of adolescents have become increasingly p.docxBullying and cyberbullying of adolescents have become increasingly p.docx
Bullying and cyberbullying of adolescents have become increasingly p.docx
 
Building an Information Technology Security Awareness an.docx
Building an Information Technology Security Awareness an.docxBuilding an Information Technology Security Awareness an.docx
Building an Information Technology Security Awareness an.docx
 
Building a company with the help of IT is really necessary as most.docx
Building a company with the help of IT is really necessary as most.docxBuilding a company with the help of IT is really necessary as most.docx
Building a company with the help of IT is really necessary as most.docx
 
Building a Comprehensive Health HistoryBuild a health histor.docx
Building a Comprehensive Health HistoryBuild a health histor.docxBuilding a Comprehensive Health HistoryBuild a health histor.docx
Building a Comprehensive Health HistoryBuild a health histor.docx
 

Recently uploaded

HỌC TỐT TIẾNG ANH 11 THEO CHƯƠNG TRÌNH GLOBAL SUCCESS ĐÁP ÁN CHI TIẾT - CẢ NĂ...
HỌC TỐT TIẾNG ANH 11 THEO CHƯƠNG TRÌNH GLOBAL SUCCESS ĐÁP ÁN CHI TIẾT - CẢ NĂ...HỌC TỐT TIẾNG ANH 11 THEO CHƯƠNG TRÌNH GLOBAL SUCCESS ĐÁP ÁN CHI TIẾT - CẢ NĂ...
HỌC TỐT TIẾNG ANH 11 THEO CHƯƠNG TRÌNH GLOBAL SUCCESS ĐÁP ÁN CHI TIẾT - CẢ NĂ...Nguyen Thanh Tu Collection
 
Roles & Responsibilities in Pharmacovigilance
Roles & Responsibilities in PharmacovigilanceRoles & Responsibilities in Pharmacovigilance
Roles & Responsibilities in PharmacovigilanceSamikshaHamane
 
Keynote by Prof. Wurzer at Nordex about IP-design
Keynote by Prof. Wurzer at Nordex about IP-designKeynote by Prof. Wurzer at Nordex about IP-design
Keynote by Prof. Wurzer at Nordex about IP-designMIPLM
 
Solving Puzzles Benefits Everyone (English).pptx
Solving Puzzles Benefits Everyone (English).pptxSolving Puzzles Benefits Everyone (English).pptx
Solving Puzzles Benefits Everyone (English).pptxOH TEIK BIN
 
ENGLISH 7_Q4_LESSON 2_ Employing a Variety of Strategies for Effective Interp...
ENGLISH 7_Q4_LESSON 2_ Employing a Variety of Strategies for Effective Interp...ENGLISH 7_Q4_LESSON 2_ Employing a Variety of Strategies for Effective Interp...
ENGLISH 7_Q4_LESSON 2_ Employing a Variety of Strategies for Effective Interp...JhezDiaz1
 
Crayon Activity Handout For the Crayon A
Crayon Activity Handout For the Crayon ACrayon Activity Handout For the Crayon A
Crayon Activity Handout For the Crayon AUnboundStockton
 
Hierarchy of management that covers different levels of management
Hierarchy of management that covers different levels of managementHierarchy of management that covers different levels of management
Hierarchy of management that covers different levels of managementmkooblal
 
Gas measurement O2,Co2,& ph) 04/2024.pptx
Gas measurement O2,Co2,& ph) 04/2024.pptxGas measurement O2,Co2,& ph) 04/2024.pptx
Gas measurement O2,Co2,& ph) 04/2024.pptxDr.Ibrahim Hassaan
 
Alper Gobel In Media Res Media Component
Alper Gobel In Media Res Media ComponentAlper Gobel In Media Res Media Component
Alper Gobel In Media Res Media ComponentInMediaRes1
 
Proudly South Africa powerpoint Thorisha.pptx
Proudly South Africa powerpoint Thorisha.pptxProudly South Africa powerpoint Thorisha.pptx
Proudly South Africa powerpoint Thorisha.pptxthorishapillay1
 
Introduction to ArtificiaI Intelligence in Higher Education
Introduction to ArtificiaI Intelligence in Higher EducationIntroduction to ArtificiaI Intelligence in Higher Education
Introduction to ArtificiaI Intelligence in Higher Educationpboyjonauth
 
AMERICAN LANGUAGE HUB_Level2_Student'sBook_Answerkey.pdf
AMERICAN LANGUAGE HUB_Level2_Student'sBook_Answerkey.pdfAMERICAN LANGUAGE HUB_Level2_Student'sBook_Answerkey.pdf
AMERICAN LANGUAGE HUB_Level2_Student'sBook_Answerkey.pdfphamnguyenenglishnb
 
Grade 9 Q4-MELC1-Active and Passive Voice.pptx
Grade 9 Q4-MELC1-Active and Passive Voice.pptxGrade 9 Q4-MELC1-Active and Passive Voice.pptx
Grade 9 Q4-MELC1-Active and Passive Voice.pptxChelloAnnAsuncion2
 
Introduction to AI in Higher Education_draft.pptx
Introduction to AI in Higher Education_draft.pptxIntroduction to AI in Higher Education_draft.pptx
Introduction to AI in Higher Education_draft.pptxpboyjonauth
 
Earth Day Presentation wow hello nice great
Earth Day Presentation wow hello nice greatEarth Day Presentation wow hello nice great
Earth Day Presentation wow hello nice greatYousafMalik24
 

Recently uploaded (20)

Model Call Girl in Bikash Puri Delhi reach out to us at 🔝9953056974🔝
Model Call Girl in Bikash Puri  Delhi reach out to us at 🔝9953056974🔝Model Call Girl in Bikash Puri  Delhi reach out to us at 🔝9953056974🔝
Model Call Girl in Bikash Puri Delhi reach out to us at 🔝9953056974🔝
 
HỌC TỐT TIẾNG ANH 11 THEO CHƯƠNG TRÌNH GLOBAL SUCCESS ĐÁP ÁN CHI TIẾT - CẢ NĂ...
HỌC TỐT TIẾNG ANH 11 THEO CHƯƠNG TRÌNH GLOBAL SUCCESS ĐÁP ÁN CHI TIẾT - CẢ NĂ...HỌC TỐT TIẾNG ANH 11 THEO CHƯƠNG TRÌNH GLOBAL SUCCESS ĐÁP ÁN CHI TIẾT - CẢ NĂ...
HỌC TỐT TIẾNG ANH 11 THEO CHƯƠNG TRÌNH GLOBAL SUCCESS ĐÁP ÁN CHI TIẾT - CẢ NĂ...
 
Roles & Responsibilities in Pharmacovigilance
Roles & Responsibilities in PharmacovigilanceRoles & Responsibilities in Pharmacovigilance
Roles & Responsibilities in Pharmacovigilance
 
TataKelola dan KamSiber Kecerdasan Buatan v022.pdf
TataKelola dan KamSiber Kecerdasan Buatan v022.pdfTataKelola dan KamSiber Kecerdasan Buatan v022.pdf
TataKelola dan KamSiber Kecerdasan Buatan v022.pdf
 
Raw materials used in Herbal Cosmetics.pptx
Raw materials used in Herbal Cosmetics.pptxRaw materials used in Herbal Cosmetics.pptx
Raw materials used in Herbal Cosmetics.pptx
 
Keynote by Prof. Wurzer at Nordex about IP-design
Keynote by Prof. Wurzer at Nordex about IP-designKeynote by Prof. Wurzer at Nordex about IP-design
Keynote by Prof. Wurzer at Nordex about IP-design
 
Solving Puzzles Benefits Everyone (English).pptx
Solving Puzzles Benefits Everyone (English).pptxSolving Puzzles Benefits Everyone (English).pptx
Solving Puzzles Benefits Everyone (English).pptx
 
ENGLISH 7_Q4_LESSON 2_ Employing a Variety of Strategies for Effective Interp...
ENGLISH 7_Q4_LESSON 2_ Employing a Variety of Strategies for Effective Interp...ENGLISH 7_Q4_LESSON 2_ Employing a Variety of Strategies for Effective Interp...
ENGLISH 7_Q4_LESSON 2_ Employing a Variety of Strategies for Effective Interp...
 
Crayon Activity Handout For the Crayon A
Crayon Activity Handout For the Crayon ACrayon Activity Handout For the Crayon A
Crayon Activity Handout For the Crayon A
 
Model Call Girl in Tilak Nagar Delhi reach out to us at 🔝9953056974🔝
Model Call Girl in Tilak Nagar Delhi reach out to us at 🔝9953056974🔝Model Call Girl in Tilak Nagar Delhi reach out to us at 🔝9953056974🔝
Model Call Girl in Tilak Nagar Delhi reach out to us at 🔝9953056974🔝
 
Hierarchy of management that covers different levels of management
Hierarchy of management that covers different levels of managementHierarchy of management that covers different levels of management
Hierarchy of management that covers different levels of management
 
Gas measurement O2,Co2,& ph) 04/2024.pptx
Gas measurement O2,Co2,& ph) 04/2024.pptxGas measurement O2,Co2,& ph) 04/2024.pptx
Gas measurement O2,Co2,& ph) 04/2024.pptx
 
Alper Gobel In Media Res Media Component
Alper Gobel In Media Res Media ComponentAlper Gobel In Media Res Media Component
Alper Gobel In Media Res Media Component
 
OS-operating systems- ch04 (Threads) ...
OS-operating systems- ch04 (Threads) ...OS-operating systems- ch04 (Threads) ...
OS-operating systems- ch04 (Threads) ...
 
Proudly South Africa powerpoint Thorisha.pptx
Proudly South Africa powerpoint Thorisha.pptxProudly South Africa powerpoint Thorisha.pptx
Proudly South Africa powerpoint Thorisha.pptx
 
Introduction to ArtificiaI Intelligence in Higher Education
Introduction to ArtificiaI Intelligence in Higher EducationIntroduction to ArtificiaI Intelligence in Higher Education
Introduction to ArtificiaI Intelligence in Higher Education
 
AMERICAN LANGUAGE HUB_Level2_Student'sBook_Answerkey.pdf
AMERICAN LANGUAGE HUB_Level2_Student'sBook_Answerkey.pdfAMERICAN LANGUAGE HUB_Level2_Student'sBook_Answerkey.pdf
AMERICAN LANGUAGE HUB_Level2_Student'sBook_Answerkey.pdf
 
Grade 9 Q4-MELC1-Active and Passive Voice.pptx
Grade 9 Q4-MELC1-Active and Passive Voice.pptxGrade 9 Q4-MELC1-Active and Passive Voice.pptx
Grade 9 Q4-MELC1-Active and Passive Voice.pptx
 
Introduction to AI in Higher Education_draft.pptx
Introduction to AI in Higher Education_draft.pptxIntroduction to AI in Higher Education_draft.pptx
Introduction to AI in Higher Education_draft.pptx
 
Earth Day Presentation wow hello nice great
Earth Day Presentation wow hello nice greatEarth Day Presentation wow hello nice great
Earth Day Presentation wow hello nice great
 

Corruption, Norms, and Legal Enforcement Evidence from Diplom.docx

  • 1. Corruption, Norms, and Legal Enforcement: Evidence from Diplomatic Parking Tickets Author(s): Raymond Fisman and Edward Miguel Source: Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 115, No. 6 (December 2007), pp. 1020-1048 Published by: The University of Chicago Press Stable URL: http://www.jstor.org/stable/10.1086/527495 . Accessed: 25/03/2015 17:53 Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available at . http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp . JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide range of content in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and facilitate new forms of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact [email protected] . The University of Chicago Press is collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend access to Journal of Political Economy. http://www.jstor.org This content downloaded from 164.107.70.42 on Wed, 25 Mar
  • 2. 2015 17:53:25 PM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions http://www.jstor.org/action/showPublisher?publisherCode=ucpr ess http://www.jstor.org/stable/10.1086/527495?origin=JSTOR-pdf http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp 1020 [ Journal of Political Economy, 2007, vol. 115, no. 6] � 2007 by The University of Chicago. All rights reserved. 0022-3808/2007/11506-0002$10.00 Corruption, Norms, and Legal Enforcement: Evidence from Diplomatic Parking Tickets Raymond Fisman Columbia University and National Bureau of Economic Research Edward Miguel University of California, Berkeley and National Bureau of Economic Research We study cultural norms and legal enforcement in controlling cor- ruption by analyzing the parking behavior of United Nations officials in Manhattan. Until 2002, diplomatic immunity protected UN dip- lomats from parking enforcement actions, so diplomats’ actions were constrained by cultural norms alone. We find a strong effect of
  • 3. cor- ruption norms: diplomats from high-corruption countries (on the basis of existing survey-based indices) accumulated significantly more unpaid parking violations. In 2002, enforcement authorities acquired the right to confiscate diplomatic license plates of violators. Unpaid violations dropped sharply in response. Cultural norms and (partic- ularly in this context) legal enforcement are both important deter- minants of corruption. We thank Stefano Dellvigna, Seema Jayachandran, Dean Yang, Luigi Zingales, and sem- inar participants at the Harvard Development Economics Lunch, Harvard Behavioral Economics Seminar, Harvard Kennedy School of Government, Harvard Political Economy discussion group, University of Michigan, London School of Economics, University of Southern California, Stockholm University, University of California, Berkeley, Northwest- ern University, University of Hawaii, Syracuse University, Harvard Business School, World Bank, University of Toronto, two anonymous referees, and Steve Levitt for helpful sug- gestions. Daniel Hartley, Adam Sacarny, and Sarath Sanga provided superb research as- sistance. We thank Gillian Sorensen for helpful discussions. We are especially grateful to the New York City Department of Finance for providing us with data on parking violations and National Public Radio for alerting us to the existence of these data. All errors are
  • 4. our own. This content downloaded from 164.107.70.42 on Wed, 25 Mar 2015 17:53:25 PM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp corruption, norms, and legal enforcement 1021 I. Introduction The underlying causes of corruption remain poorly understood and widely debated. Yet the study of corruption beyond the realm of opinion surveys is still in its infancy, and there is little firm evidence relating corruption to real-world causal factors. Notably, both social norms and legal enforcement are often mentioned as primary contributors to cor- ruption in both the academic literature and the popular press, yet there is no evidence beyond the most casual of cross-country empirics.1 Distinguishing between the effects of social norms and legal enforce- ment is confounded by problems of identification: societies that collec- tively place less importance on rooting out corruption, and thus have weak anticorruption social norms, may simultaneously have less legal
  • 5. enforcement. Understanding the relative importance of these potential causes of corruption is of central importance in reforming public in- stitutions to improve governance and in the current debate in foreign aid policy. The World Bank emphasizes effectiveness of legal enforce- ment, but social reformers have highlighted the importance of changing civic norms in anticorruption efforts.2 We develop an empirical approach for evaluating the role of both social norms and legal enforcement in corruption by studying parking violations among United Nations diplomats living in New York City. Mission personnel and their families benefit from diplomatic immunity, a privilege that allowed them to avoid paying parking fines prior to November 2002. The act of parking illegally fits well with a standard definition of corruption, that is, “the abuse of entrusted power for pri- vate gain,”3 suggesting that the comparison of parking violations by diplomats from different societies serves as a plausible measure of the extent of corruption social norms or a corruption “culture.” This setting has a number of advantages for studying corruption norms. Most important, our approach avoids the problem of differential legal enforcement levels across countries and more generally
  • 6. strips out enforcement effects prior to the New York City government’s enforce- 1 See Lambsdorff (2006) for an overview of findings on the determinants of corruption based on cross-country comparisons. Witzel (2005) provides one of many discussions on the topic in the popular press. The effects of legal enforcement on crime in general have been much examined theoretically, beginning with Becker (1968). Theories of norms and corruption are presented in Mauro (2004), which discusses models of multiple equilibria in corruption levels that could be interpreted as capturing corruption culture, and in Tirole (1996), which develops a model of bureaucratic collective reputation that also implies persistent corruption. 2 One successful anticorruption reformer who focused on changing norms as an element of reform, and who is well cited in the international media, is Antanas Mockus, the former mayor of Bogotá, Colombia (Rockwell 2004). 3 This is the definition used by the leading anticorruption organization Transparency International (see http://ww1.transparency.org/about_ti/mission.html). This content downloaded from 164.107.70.42 on Wed, 25 Mar 2015 17:53:25 PM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp
  • 7. q Highlight q Highlight q Highlight q Highlight q Highlight q Highlight q Highlight q Highlight q Highlight 1022 journal of political economy ment actions of November 2002, since there was essentially no enforce- ment of diplomats’ parking violations before this time. We thus interpret diplomats’ behavior as reflecting their underlying propensity to
  • 8. break rules for private gain when enforcement is not a consideration. Dip- lomats to UN missions are also a relatively homogeneous group, selected for similar official duties in New York. Additionally, because UN missions are overwhelmingly colocated in Midtown Manhattan—87 percent of missions are located within 1 mile of the UN complex—we avoid many concerns of unobserved differences in parking availability across geo- graphic settings. This approach allows us to construct a “revealed preference” measure of corruption among government officials across 149 countries, based on real rule breaking in parking.4 Corruption levels, particularly across countries, have proved challenging to measure objectively because of the illicit nature of corrupt activities. In our main empirical results, we find that this parking violation corruption measure is strongly positively correlated with other (survey-based) country corruption measures and that this relationship is robust to conditioning on region fixed effects, country income, and a wide range of other controls, including govern- ment employee salary measures. This suggests that home country cor- ruption norms are an important predictor of propensity to
  • 9. behave cor- ruptly among diplomats: those from low-corruption countries (e.g., Norway) behave remarkably well even in situations in which there are no legal consequences, whereas those from high-corruption countries (e.g., Nigeria) commit many violations. It also goes somewhat against the predictions of standard economic models of crime in situations of zero legal enforcement (e.g., Becker 1968), which would predict high rates of parking violations among all diplomats in the absence of enforcement. The natural experiment of New York City diplomatic parking privi- leges also allows for a direct comparison of the effects of norms versus enforcement by exploiting a sharp increase in the legal punishment for parking violations. Starting in November 2002, New York City began stripping the official diplomatic license plates from vehicles that accu- mulated more than three unpaid parking violations. This credible in- crease in enforcement—the city government made examples of 30 coun- tries by having their vehicles’ plates stripped in October 20025—led to immediate and massive declines of approximately 98 percent in parking violations (see fig. 1 below). Thus, cultural norms matter for
  • 10. crime, but so does enforcement, a finding that resonates with the work of Becker 4 In this sense, our corruption measure is conceptually similar to the Economist magazine’s “Big Mac Index” as a measure of country purchasing power parity. 5 Refer to Fries (2002) for an example of media coverage. This content downloaded from 164.107.70.42 on Wed, 25 Mar 2015 17:53:25 PM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp q Highlight q Highlight q Highlight q Highlight q Highlight q Highlight q
  • 11. Highlight q Highlight q Highlight q Highlight corruption, norms, and legal enforcement 1023 (1968), Levitt (1997, 2004), Di Tella and Schargrodsky (2003), and others on the responsiveness of crime to punishment. In our setting, the impact of legal enforcement appears larger than the effects of var- iation in cultural norms across countries. The main theoretical implication of these empirical patterns, taken together, is that both cultural norms and legal enforcement play key roles in government officials’ corruption decisions. They suggest that both factors should be taken seriously in debates about the causes of corruption and the policy measures to combat it. Since the parking violations data exist at the individual level for all UN mission diplomats present in New York City (numbering roughly
  • 12. 1,700 at the start of our study period), we can examine how individual behavior evolves over time. For diplomats from high-corruption coun- tries of origin, a model of convergence to U.S. corruption norms would (presumably) predict a decline in the rate of parking violations over time, as tenure in the United States increases. By contrast, a model of convergence to the “zero-enforcement” norm discussed above would imply an increase in violations over time, particularly for officials from low-corruption countries. We find evidence that the frequency of vio- lations increases with tenure in New York City and that these increases are particularly large for diplomats from low-corruption countries, sug- gesting that there is partial convergence to the zero-enforcement norm over time. Beyond contributing to the large literature in economics on the de- terminants of legal compliance, our work is part of a growing body of research on the importance of cultural background in explaining in- dividual behavior. Much of this work compares the outcomes and actions of immigrant groups from different countries. For example, Borjas (2000) finds that home country attributes are predictive of immigrants’
  • 13. economic achievement. In the social domain, Fernandez and Fogli (2006) show that fertility rates among Americans are correlated with fertility in their countries of ancestry. In work also related to ours, Ichino and Maggi (2000) study absenteeism and misconduct of employees at an Italian bank and find that region of origin within Italy predicts shirking. We also seek to contribute to the growing empirical literature on corruption specifically. Other recent empirical research emphasizes the importance of developing corruption measures based on real- world de- cisions rather than survey responses; see Reinikka and Svensson (2004) and Olken (2006) for discussions. This article is the first to our knowl- edge to develop a revealed preference measure of corruption that is comparable across countries. Finally, the importance of norm compli- ance and nonselfish behavior has been documented in the laboratory This content downloaded from 164.107.70.42 on Wed, 25 Mar 2015 17:53:25 PM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp q
  • 14. Highlight q Highlight q Highlight q Highlight q Highlight 1024 journal of political economy (see, e.g., Ledyard 1995), and more recently Levitt (2006) provides evidence on norms of nonselfish behavior in the field. The rest of the article proceeds as follows: Section II describes the diplomatic parking situation in New York City and the violations data, Section III discusses the rest of the data set, Section IV contains the empirical results, and Section V presents conclusions. II. Diplomatic Parking Violations in New York City Diplomatic representatives to the United Nations and their families are given immunity from prosecution or lawsuits in the United States. The original intent of these laws was to protect diplomats from
  • 15. mistreatment abroad, especially in countries not on friendly terms with the home country.6 However, these days diplomatic immunity is more commonly viewed as the “best free parking pass in town” (BBC News 1998). Dip- lomatic vehicles in New York possess license plates tagged with the letter D, which signals diplomatic status.7 While these vehicles may be ticketed, the car’s registrant is shielded from any punishment for nonpayment of the ticket. Thus one immediate implication of diplomatic immunity— not just in New York, but also in most other capitals (e.g., London [BBC News 1998], Paris [Agence Presse–France 2005], and Seoul [Korea Times 1999])—has been that it allows diplomats to park illegally but never suffer the threat of legal punishment, leaving a “paper trail” of the illegal acts (see http://www.state.gov/m/ds/immunities/c9127.htm). To illus- trate the magnitude of the problem, between November 1997 and the end of 2002 in New York City, diplomats accumulated over 150,000 unpaid parking tickets, resulting in outstanding fines of more than $18 million. The New York City parking violations data are at the level of the individual unpaid violation.8 Drivers have 30 days to pay a
  • 16. ticket before it goes into default, at which point an additional penalty is levied (gen- erally 110 percent of the initial fine). Diplomats then receive an addi- tional 70 days to pay the ticket plus this penalty before it is recorded in our data set as an unpaid violation in default. The information on each violation includes the license plate number; the name and country of origin of the car’s registrant; the date, time, and location of the 6 While the origins of diplomatic protection date back many centuries, the current incarnation is found in the 1961 Vienna Convention on Diplomatic Relations. See http://www.un.int/usa/host_dip.htm for the full text. 7 Note that while the vehicle’s diplomatic status is revealed by the license plate, the country codes denoting particular countries are unrelated to country names; e.g., the code (at the start of the plate number) for Mozambique is QS and the code for Nigeria is JF. 8 We gratefully acknowledge the New York City Department of Finance, in particular Sam Miller and Gerald Koszner, for compiling these data. This content downloaded from 164.107.70.42 on Wed, 25 Mar 2015 17:53:25 PM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
  • 17. http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp q Highlight q Highlight q Highlight q Highlight q Highlight corruption, norms, and legal enforcement 1025 violation; the fine and penalty levied; and the amount paid (if any). The most common violation in our data was parking in a No Standing— Loading Zone (43 percent of violations), which is typically parking in someone else’s driveway or business entrance. The remainder were spread across a range of violation types that imply varying degrees of social harm:9 fines for expired meters accounted for 6 percent of the total, double-parking 5 percent, and parking in front of a fire hydrant 7 percent, for instance. Also note that in 20 percent of violations the
  • 18. registrant is the mission itself, signifying an official rather than personal vehicle. While the majority of violations are located within a mile of either the country’s UN mission or the UN complex, many are com- mitted in other parts of the city. We return to the issue of violation location below. The total period of coverage in our data set is November 24, 1997, to November 21, 2005. (Refer to the Data Appendix for more on the data set.) A crucial change in legal enforcement took place in October 2002, when the State Department gave New York City permission to revoke the official diplomatic plates of vehicles with three or more outstanding unpaid violations (Steinhauer 2002). In addition, the Clinton- Schumer Amendment (named after the two New York senators), put in place at the same time, allowed the city to petition the State Department to have 110 percent of the total amount due deducted from U.S. foreign aid to the offending diplomats’ country, although this latter punishment was never invoked in practice (Singleton 2004). In constructing our data set, we generate separate measures of the extent of unpaid violations for the pre-enforcement (November 1997–
  • 19. October 2002) and postenforcement (November 2002–November 2005) periods. In each case, we employ the total number of unpaid diplomatic parking violations for a particular country. In order to control for base- line mission size, we calculate the total number of UN permanent mis- sion staff with diplomatic privileges using the UN Blue Book for May 1998. Published twice annually, the Blue Book lists all UN mission staff, as well as their official titles. We additionally use UN Blue Books for 1997–2005 to track the UN tenure of individual diplomats. Fortunately, the Blue Books generally use consistent spellings across editions, facil- itating automated matching across time. In most cases, the spelling and format were also consistent with the names in the parking violations data; the algorithm automatically matched 61 percent of diplomats in the violations database. The first Blue Book we use is from January 1997, 9 Almost all parking violations in the data set resulted in fines of US$55, making it impossible to assess the extent of social damage by violations’ relative prices. This content downloaded from 164.107.70.42 on Wed, 25 Mar 2015 17:53:25 PM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
  • 20. http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp q Highlight 1026 journal of political economy and we use this as our start date for calculating tenure at the United Nations.10 We obtained data on the number of diplomatic license plates regis- tered to each mission from the U.S. State Department’s Office of Foreign Missions, and we use these data as a control variable in some specifi- cations. Unfortunately, these data are available only for 2006, though we were assured that the numbers are largely stable over time.11 Table 1 presents the annual number of violations per diplomat by country during the pre-enforcement period (November 1997– October 2002) and the postenforcement period (November 2002– November 2005), along with the total number of diplomats in May 1998. Overall, the basic pattern accords reasonably well with common perceptions of corruption across countries. The worst parking violators—the 10 worst (in order) are Kuwait, Egypt, Chad, Sudan, Bulgaria,
  • 21. Mozambique, Al- bania, Angola, Senegal, and Pakistan—all rank poorly in cross- country corruption rankings (described below), with the exception of Kuwait. The raw correlation between the country corruption rankings and pre- enforcement parking violations per diplomat is �0.18, and that between the corruption ranking and postenforcement violations per capita is �0.24. While many of the countries with zero violations accord well with intuition (e.g., the Scandinavian countries, Canada, and Japan), there are a number of surprises. Some of these are countries with very small missions (e.g., Burkina Faso and the Central African Republic), and a few others have high rates of parking violations but do pay off the fines (these are Bahrain, Malaysia, Oman, and Turkey; we return to this issue below). The smallest missions may plausibly have fewer violations since each mission is given two legal parking spaces at the United Nations, and this may suffice if the country has very few diplomats. Figure 1 plots the total violations per month during November 1997– November 2005. There are two clear declines in the number of viola- tions. The first comes in September 2001, corresponding to the period following the World Trade Center attack. The second and
  • 22. extremely pronounced decline coincides with increased legal enforcement of dip- lomatic parking violators. 10 That is, we cannot distinguish among arrival times pre-1997, and all individuals in- cluded in the January 1997 Blue Book are coded as arriving in that month. As a robustness check, we also limit the sample only to diplomats who were not yet present in New York in the 1997 Blue Book (reducing the sample slightly), which allows us to more accurately capture arrival date. 11 We thank Murray Smith of the U.S. Office of Foreign Services for these data and for many useful conversations. This content downloaded from 164.107.70.42 on Wed, 25 Mar 2015 17:53:25 PM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp q Highlight q Highlight q Highlight q Highlight
  • 45. 2015 17:53:25 PM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp 1028 T A B L E 1 (C on tin ue d ) Pa rk in g V io la
  • 67. 16 � 1. 00 IT A 48 L ib er ia 13 .7 .8 7 6 1. 44 L B R This content downloaded from 164.107.70.42 on Wed, 25 Mar 2015 17:53:25 PM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
  • 90. a 6. 2 .5 5 18 .1 7 IN D This content downloaded from 164.107.70.42 on Wed, 25 Mar 2015 17:53:25 PM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp 1030 T A B L E 1 (C on
  • 113. .2 6 G U Y This content downloaded from 164.107.70.42 on Wed, 25 Mar 2015 17:53:25 PM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp 1031 10 9 A us tr ia 2. 2 .5 1 21 �
  • 138. This content downloaded from 164.107.70.42 on Wed, 25 Mar 2015 17:53:25 PM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp T A B L E 1 (C on tin ue d ) Pa rk in g V io la ti
  • 150. m or e co rr up ti on . This content downloaded from 164.107.70.42 on Wed, 25 Mar 2015 17:53:25 PM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp corruption, norms, and legal enforcement 1033 Fig. 1.—Total monthly New York City parking violations by diplomats, 1997–2005 (ver- tical axis on log scale). III. Cross-Country Data We employ country-level data on economic, political, and social char- acteristics and in particular consider data on country corruption levels using the measure in Kaufmann, Kraay, and Mastruzzi (2005) from 1998, the earliest year with wide country coverage. This is a
  • 151. composite cor- ruption index that is essentially the first principal component of a num- ber of other commonly used corruption indices, which are usually sub- jective measures based on surveys of country experts and investors. By definition, therefore, the Kaufmann et al. measure is highly correlated with the commonly used indices and is extremely highly correlated ( ) with the Transparency International ratings from the samer p 0.97 year. For ease of interpretation, we reverse the sign of the original mea- sure so that higher values indicate greater corruption. By construction, the mean value of this measure across all countries in their sample is zero with standard deviation one, and it ranges from �2.6 to �1.6 in our slightly restricted sample of countries. The main advantages of this country measure are that its method of aggregation is clearly defined relative to the Transparency International measure, and it has broader country coverage than other indices. Our sample consists of all countries that had 1998 populations greater than 500,000 according to the World Development Indicators, and for which basic country-level data were This content downloaded from 164.107.70.42 on Wed, 25 Mar 2015 17:53:25 PM
  • 152. All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp q Highlight 1034 journal of political economy TABLE 2 Descriptive Statistics Variable Mean Standard Deviation Observations A. Country-Level Data Unpaid New York City parking violations:a 11/1997–11/2002 977.9 2,000.9 149 11/2002–11/2005 11.3 18.4 149 Unpaid and paid New York City parking violations, 11/1997–11/2002a 1,066.2 2,021.4 149 After-hours New York city parking viola- tions, 11/1997–11/2002 a 40.6 72.7 149 Diplomats in the country UN mission, 1998b 11.8 11.1 149 Number of license plates registered to the country’s UN mission, 2006c 10.5 14.0 139
  • 153. Country corruption index, 1998d .01 1.01 149 Log per capita income (1998 US$)e 7.35 1.59 149 Average government wage/country per capita income, early 1990sf 2.83 2.38 92 Log weighted distance between populationsg 9.12 .41 149 Log total trade with the United States (1998 US$)h 20.3 2.7 146 Received U.S. economic aid (indicator), 1998i .69 .46 147 Received U.S. military aid (indicator), 1998i .63 .49 147 B. Diplomat-Level Data Monthly unpaid New York City parking violations:a 11/1997–11/2002 .90 3.30 25,123 11/2002–11/2005 .02 .19 15,806 Length of time at the UN mission in New York City (in months)b 7.7 12.4 40,929 a Source: New York City, Parking Violations Database (provided to the authors by the New York City Department of Finance). b Source: United Nations Blue Books, 1997–2005. c Source: U.S. Department of State Office of Foreign Missions (provided to the authors by Deputy Director Murray
  • 154. Smith). d Composite index from Kaufmann et al. (2005), but here higher values indicate more corruption. e Source: World Development Indicators (2005). f Source: Schiavo-Campo et al. (1999); exact year differs by country. g Source: Mayer and Zignago (2005). h Source: U.S. International Trade Commission (2006). i Data from Kuziemko and Werker (2006). available. Table 2 presents summary statistics for both the country-level and diplomat-level variables. We include a number of other variables that may affect incentives to comply with local laws. From the data set used by Kuziemko and Werker (2006), we generate an indicator variable denoting whether the country received foreign aid from the United States in 1998. We similarly gen- erate a pair of indicator variables for military and economic aid, since This content downloaded from 164.107.70.42 on Wed, 25 Mar 2015 17:53:25 PM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp q Highlight q
  • 155. Highlight q Highlight corruption, norms, and legal enforcement 1035 these two types of aid may reflect different geopolitical interests: while economic aid recipients may feel beholden to the United States, those receiving military aid are typically countries that the United States seeks as strategic allies. Finally, we include the logarithm of 1998 GDP per capita in U.S. dollars (taken from the World Development Indicators) in most spec- ifications to control for income effects. Country-level income per capita is strongly correlated with corruption and with the rule of law, and some argue that income is influenced by underlying corruption levels, com- plicating efforts to disentangle corruption effects from income effects. As we discuss below, despite this strong correlation, the main corruption results are robust to including income controls. Second, we include the ratio of government bureaucrats’ salaries to GDP per capita (using data from Schiavo-Campo, de Tommaso, and Mukherjee [1999]) for the early
  • 156. 1990s (exact year differs by country) to account for the possibility that bureaucrats occupy different positions in the national income distribution. IV. Empirical Results A count model analysis is appropriate given the dependent variable, the total number of unpaid parking violations by country. We focus on the negative binomial model (the Poisson model can be rejected at high levels of confidence because of overdispersion of the parking tickets outcome variable; result not shown). In the main econometric specifi- cation for the cross-country analysis, the dependent variable is Total Unpaid Parking Violationsit, where i denotes the country. There are two time periods t per country, one for the pre-enforcement period and one for the postenforcement period. Standard errors are robustly estimated, and the disturbance terms for a country are allowed to be correlated. The vector of explanatory variables is ′b Corruption � b Enforcement � b Diplomats � X g,1 i 2 it 3 i i where Corruption is the 1998 country corruption index; Enforcement is an indicator for the post–October 2002 period, when legal enforce-
  • 157. ment increased sharply against diplomatic parking violators; and X is a vector of other country controls, including the log of 1998 GDP per capita, and region fixed effects,12 among others depending on the specification. The New York City unpaid parking violations measure is robustly 12 United Nations region code data, available at http://unstats.un.org/unsd/methods/ m49/m49regin.htm, were used to classify countries into the following regions: (1) North America (including Caribbean), (2) South America, (3) Europe, (4) Asia, (5) Oceania, (6) Africa, and (7) Middle East. This content downloaded from 164.107.70.42 on Wed, 25 Mar 2015 17:53:25 PM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp q Highlight q Highlight q Highlight q Highlight
  • 158. q Highlight q Highlight q Highlight q Highlight q Highlight 1036 journal of political economy positively correlated with the existing subjective country corruption in- dex conditional on the number of UN mission diplomats for that coun- try in New York City (table 3, regression 1). The relationship is roughly linear (fig. 2). The coefficient implies that the increase in the corruption index associated with going from a highly corrupt country such as Ni- geria (corruption score �1.01) to a largely uncorrupt country such as Norway (score �2.35) is associated with a large drop of 48 log points # 3.36 p 161 log points, or approximately 80 percent, in the average rate of diplomatic parking violations. The result is nearly
  • 159. unchanged if Kuwait, the country with the most parking violations per diplomat, is dropped from the sample (not shown). Parking violations also plummet in the postenforcement period, by over 98 percent on average, indi- cating that legal enforcement is also highly influential. The coefficient estimate on the country corruption index is robust to the inclusion of log per capita income (table 3, regression 2). This pattern argues strongly against the explanation that richer countries are simply able to purchase more parking spots for their diplomats, in which case we would expect a weakening of the relationship between country corruption and parking violations and a negative coefficient estimate on country income, but we find neither. The result is also robust to controlling for region fixed effects (regression 3). The Middle East and Africa are the regions with the greatest average number of unpaid park- ing violations relative to the reference region (North America and the Caribbean). The inclusion of higher-order polynomial controls for in- come (regression 4) and an interaction between country corruption and the postenforcement period (regression 5) also has little effect on the partial correlation of the corruption index with parking
  • 160. violations committed. The interaction term between country corruption and the postenforcement period indicator variable has little predictive power, indicating a largely stable relationship across the pre- and postenforce- ment periods (see fig. 3). The results are robust to including the average government wage relative to per capita income (table 4, regression 1) and also to the number of vehicles registered to each mission (regression 2).13 The inclusion of paid violations in our parking violations measure has no effect on the main results (regression 3), further arguing against the possibility that our country corruption measure is picking up an income effect rather than a corruption effect. There is also strong evidence that many violations are not work re- lated. We focus on the subset of violations committed between the night- time hours of 10:00 p.m. and 6:00 a.m. at a distance of more than five 13 A specification using fixed effects for the number of vehicles per mission generates similar results (not shown). This content downloaded from 164.107.70.42 on Wed, 25 Mar 2015 17:53:25 PM
  • 161. All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp q Highlight q Highlight q Highlight q Highlight q Highlight q Highlight TABLE 3 Country Characteristics and Unpaid New York City Parking Violations, November 1997 to November 2005 Dependent Variable: Unpaid Parking Violations (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) Country corruption index, 1998 .48*** .57*** .57*** .56** .57*
  • 162. (.18) (.22) (.21) (.28) (.30) Postenforcement period indicator (post-11/2002) �4.41*** �4.41*** �4.21*** �4.43*** �4.41*** (.21) (.21) (.13) (.20) (.21) Country corruption index # postenforcement period �.01 (.28) Diplomats .05** .04** .05*** .05** .04** (.02) (.02) (.02) (.02) (.02) Log per capita income (1998 US$) .06 .09 64.2* .06 (.14) (.14) (36.9) (.14) Africa region indicator variable 2.86*** (.48) Asia region indicator variable 1.99*** (.50) Europe region indicator variable 2.24*** (.55) Latin America region indi- cator variable 1.67***
  • 163. (.56) Middle East region indica- tor variable 3.23*** (.60) Oceania region indicator variable 1.51** (.64) Log per capita income (1998 US$) polynomials (quadratic, cubic, quartic) No No No Yes No Observations 298 298 298 298 298 Log pseudolikelihood �1,570.21 �1,570.07 �1,547.69 �1,567.56 �1,570.07 Note.—Negative binomial regressions. White robust standard errors are in parentheses. Disturbance terms are clus- tered by country (there are two observations per country: pre- enforcement and postenforcement). The omitted region category is North America/Caribbean. * Statistically significantly different from zero at 90 percent confidence. ** Statistically significantly different from zero at 95 percent confidence. *** Statistically significantly different from zero at 99 percent confidence. This content downloaded from 164.107.70.42 on Wed, 25 Mar 2015 17:53:25 PM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
  • 164. http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp q Highlight q Highlight q Highlight 1038 journal of political economy Fig. 2.—Country corruption and unpaid New York City parking violations per diplomat (in logs), pre-enforcement (November 1997 to November 2002). Country abbreviations are presented in table 1. The line is the quadratic regression fit. The y-axis is log(1 � Annual NYC Parking Violations/Diplomat). city blocks (roughly one-quarter mile) away from the UN complex, where most of the missions are centered. We find that a similar rela- tionship between the country corruption and legal enforcement terms also holds for this subset of violations (table 4, regression 4).14 The strong relationship between the parking violation corruption measure and the country corruption index is robust to different func- tional forms. It also holds if the dependent variable is log(1 �
  • 165. Unpaid Parking Violations) across specifications (table 4, regression 5) and is 14 The results in tables 3 and 4 are nearly identical if distance from the country’s UN mission to the UN Plaza is included as an additional explanatory variable (results not shown). We also examined the most socially egregious New York City parking violations. While impoverished diplomats from poor countries might be forced to park illegally in order to avoid the extra expense of renting a parking spot, they could still try to do so in a manner that avoids excessive negative social externalities. As indications of “extreme” violations, we considered (i) parking in front of a fire hydrant and (ii) violations for double-parking on east-west streets between Tenth and 100th streets in Manhattan, rela- tively narrow streets where double-parking can completely block passage. The main results hold robustly for both types of violations (not shown); in other words, diplomats from high-corruption countries are much more likely to commit the most egregious violations. Hence our results are not driven solely by behaviors causing minimal social harm (i.e., an expired meter in a legal parking spot) or those in which it may be unclear to the diplomat that he or she is generating negative externalities. This content downloaded from 164.107.70.42 on Wed, 25 Mar 2015 17:53:25 PM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
  • 166. http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp q Highlight corruption, norms, and legal enforcement 1039 Fig. 3.—Country corruption and unpaid New York City parking violations per diplomat (in logs), postenforcement (November 2002 to November 2005). Country abbreviations are presented in table 1. The line is the quadratic regression fit. The y-axis is log(1 � Annual NYC Parking Violations/Diplomat). similar for an ordinary least squares (OLS) specification with unpaid violations as the dependent variable (regression 6). Several measures of “proximity” to the United States are correlated with fewer unpaid parking violations. First, the log of the weighted average distance between a country’s population and the U.S. popula- tion15 is strongly positively correlated with parking violations (table 4, regression 7), indicating that diplomats from countries in closer geo- graphic proximity to the United States have many fewer New York City violations. We do not have a definitive explanation for this pattern; however, we note that it is not driven by trade volumes, which are not
  • 167. a statistically significant predictor of parking violations (coefficient es- timate 0.04, standard error 0.07). Migration, tourism, and some broader cultural affinity between the countries are other possible explanations. Countries that receive U.S. economic aid are significantly less likely to commit diplomatic parking violations (with a large effect of 65 log 15 Distance from the United States is taken from Mayer and Zignago (2005). Their measure uses city-level data to assess the geographic distribution of population inside each nation and calculates the distance between two countries on the basis of bilateral distances between the largest cities of those two countries, those intercity distances being weighted by the share of the city in the overall country’s population. This content downloaded from 164.107.70.42 on Wed, 25 Mar 2015 17:53:25 PM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp q Highlight q Highlight 1040
  • 189. e/ co un tr y pe r ca pi ta in co m e .1 5* * (. 06 ) This content downloaded from 164.107.70.42 on Wed, 25 Mar 2015 17:53:25 PM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp
  • 205. n fi de n ce . This content downloaded from 164.107.70.42 on Wed, 25 Mar 2015 17:53:25 PM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp 1042 journal of political economy points), suggesting that the goodwill engendered by these ties may help to limit abuse of diplomatic privileges in New York and pointing to the broader role of sentiment in driving norm compliance.16 Since we can follow individual diplomats during their tenure at the United Nations, we examine the related question of how diplomat be- havior evolves while in New York City. Conceptually, the relative plau- sibility of socialization to U.S. norms versus convergence to a uniform high-corruption norm is unclear. If convergence is to U.S. corruption norms, individuals from high-corruption countries (e.g.,
  • 206. Nigeria) should have declining parking violations over time, but there should be no change in behavior for diplomats from the low-corruption societies (e.g., Norway). Alternatively, individuals may begin their stay in New York City unsure as to the extent to which they can get away with violations. Once they successfully “got away with it” a few times (or heard stories about others doing so), diplomats may become bolder in their violations. Thus convergence to this zero-enforcement norm predicts increasing viola- tions over time, particularly among diplomats from less corrupt countries. In practice, to estimate these effects, we use a negative binomial re- gression like that discussed above, but with observations at the diplomat- month level of analysis. We include month-year fixed effects ( ). Theat two key explanatory variables are the effect of increased time spent working as a consular official in New York City on parking violations and the differential time effect for diplomats from countries with higher corruption (the interaction effect of time spent working in New York City with the country corruption index). Disturbance terms are allowed to be correlated across the monthly observations for the same
  • 207. individual. The parking violations included in the individual-level analysis are a subset of those used at the country level: violations committed using official consular vehicles are excluded below since they cannot be matched to any one diplomat. The frequency of unpaid violations increases rapidly and statistically significantly with tenure in New York City (table 5, regression 1), seem- ingly ruling out convergence to the U.S. norm of rule adherence. On average, parking violations increase by 8.4 percent with each additional 16 An additional direct measure of affinity is provided by the Pew Global Attitudes Survey from 2002 (the earliest year that the survey was performed), based on responses to the question “Please tell me if you have a very favorable, somewhat favorable, somewhat un- favorable, or very unfavorable opinion of the United States.” This is coded to take on values from one (most favorable) to four (least favorable) and then averaged across re- spondents. In some specifications, the anti-U.S. sentiment term is a large and statistically significant predictor of more parking violations (see Fisman and Miguel 2006). However, the result does not robustly hold when the negative binomial specification is used, and thus we do not emphasize it. A main limitation of the analysis with the Pew data is the
  • 208. small sample of only 42 countries. The data are available at http://pewglobal.org/. This content downloaded from 164.107.70.42 on Wed, 25 Mar 2015 17:53:25 PM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp q Highlight q Highlight q Highlight q Highlight q Highlight q Highlight q Highlight q Highlight corruption, norms, and legal enforcement 1043
  • 209. TABLE 5 Unpaid Parking Violations at the Diplomat level, November 1997 to November 2005 Dependent Variable: Unpaid Parking Viola- tions (Monthly) Negative Binomial (1) Negative Binomial (2) Country corruption index, 1998 .150 .390*** (.120) (.117) Log length of time in New York City (in months) .084*** .090*** (.005) (.006) Log length of time in New York City # coun- try corruption index �.027*** (.006) Month fixed effects Yes Yes Observations (diplomats) 40,929
  • 210. (5,338) 40,929 (5,338) Log pseudolikelihood �23,733 �23,621 Note.—White robust standard errors are in parentheses. Disturbance terms are clustered by country. Observations are at the diplomat-month level. Month fixed effects are included in all regressions (thus the postenforcement indicator is not included). The log per capita income (1998 US$) term is included as a control in cols. 1–2 (results not shown). * Statistically significantly different from zero at 90 percent confidence. ** Statistically significantly different from zero at 95 percent confidence. *** Statistically significantly different from zero at 99 percent confidence. month a diplomat lives in New York, perhaps as he or she learns about the reality of diplomatic immunity. Diplomats from low- corruption coun- tries show the most rapid proportional increases in violations over time (regression 2), consistent with partial convergence to the zero- enforce- ment norm, although the large proportional increases among diplomats from low-corruption countries are from a much lower base rate of vi- olations. This increase in parking violations among those from low- corruption countries occurs almost entirely in the pre-
  • 211. enforcement pe- riod (result not shown), an indication that their attachment to home country anticorruption norms was partly eroded by time spent in New York City’s lawless pre–November 2002 parking environment.17 Alternative explanations.—Informal or formal social sanctions against diplomats in the home country could be partially responsible for re- straining parking violations through, for example, public embarrass- ment in the media upon returning home or punishment by the dip- 17 Similar results hold with alternative specifications, including a linear regression model (not shown). When diplomat fixed effects are included in a linear model, the coefficient estimate on the interaction between months in New York City and country corruption is negative but no longer statistically significant. Results are virtually identical if individuals who arrived only after the earliest UN Blue Book was published are excluded, which allows us to more accurately capture tenure in New York City (not shown). This content downloaded from 164.107.70.42 on Wed, 25 Mar 2015 17:53:25 PM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp
  • 212. q Highlight 1044 journal of political economy lomatic service. If the potential response of others in the home country, either informally or formally, is responsible for limiting parking viola- tions, then diplomats’ behaviors are better interpreted as an indication of their home country’s cultural tolerance for corruption rather than their own personal values. However, this is still consistent with the basic interpretation of the level of New York City parking violations as a re- vealed preference measure of country corruption norms in the absence of formal legal enforcement. In such cases, diplomats’ behaviors are better interpreted as an indication of their home country’s norms or culture rather than their own personal values. Several findings argue somewhat against this interpretation that non- legal punishments such as media embarrassment or workplace punish- ment are the main drivers of our findings. First, a Lexis-Nexis search of 504 European news outlets (English language or in translation) using the terms “diplomats” and “parking” and “New York” yielded only 25
  • 213. stories during the entire study period, and these stories were concen- trated in just four countries (the United Kingdom, Germany, France, and Russia). Further, with the exception of several Russian articles, the stories were about the general problem of diplomatic parking violations in New York City and the 2002 crackdown rather than reporting on the behavior of home country diplomats. The possibility of sanctions for returning diplomats who accumulated parking tickets while abroad is apparently not a leading media issue, in Europe at least. Second, we considered whether unpaid parking violations early in an official’s tenure at the United Nations in New York City are correlated with the length of his employment there, and further whether these early violations interact in any way with corruption in the country of origin (i.e., perhaps violators from low-corruption countries could be punished by their government and sent home early). We find no evi- dence for any such effects of parking violations on diplomat tenure (regressions not shown). Obviously, neither of these two findings is completely conclusive in terms of pinning down the exact channel for the culture results. In
  • 214. equilibrium the number of violations committed could reflect choices made, in part, to avoid home country sanctions. But they are certainly consistent with the widely held view among New York City officials that home country enforcement is typically weak or nonexistent.18 A related concern is that public pressure could have a larger effect on diplomats’ choices in a more democratic political setting. However, we do not find that the number of parking violations is statistically significantly related 18 Gillian Sorensen, former New York City Commissioner for the United Nations and Consular Affairs in the 1980s, claims that during her tenure UN missions in New York City rarely, if ever, punished their employees for parking tickets, even in the most egregious cases (personal communication, February 8, 2007). This content downloaded from 164.107.70.42 on Wed, 25 Mar 2015 17:53:25 PM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp corruption, norms, and legal enforcement 1045 to democracy (as measured by the Polity IV democracy scale in 1998), nor is the coefficient on corruption affected at all by its inclusion (re-
  • 215. gressions not shown).19 V. Conclusion We exploit a unique natural experiment—the stationing in New York City of thousands of government officials from 149 countries around the world—in a setting of zero legal enforcement of parking violations to construct a revealed preference measure of official corruption, and then estimate how behavior changes when legal enforcement increased. We find that the number of diplomatic parking violations is strongly correlated with existing measures of home country corruption. This finding suggests that cultural or social norms related to corruption are quite persistent: even when stationed thousands of miles away, diplomats behave in a manner highly reminiscent of government officials in the home country. Norms related to corruption are apparently deeply in- grained, and factors other than legal enforcement are important de- terminants of corruption behavior. Nonetheless, increased legal en- forcement is also highly influential: parking violations fell by over 98 percent after enforcement was introduced. New York City is an attractive location to study increased enforcement relative to many less developed
  • 216. countries, where official changes “on the books” may not always translate into greater actual enforcement on the ground. The result on sticky corruption cultures raises the critical question of whether there are policy interventions that can modify corruption norms over time. For example, the Bloomberg administration’s enforcement efforts in New York City in 2002 were extremely successful in changing diplomats’ behaviors, and it would be useful to know whether these changes might additionally have had persistent effects on norms once individuals become habituated to rule-compliant behavior. Such long- run effects of temporary interventions necessarily rely on a shift in norms (or tastes) and would be consistent with the findings of Di Tella and Schargrodsky (2003) on the persistent effects of auditing on corruption 19 A final consideration is whether there is a differential selection mechanism for UN diplomats across countries that might account for the pattern we observe. In particular, it would be problematic if the relatively more corrupt government officials (within the distribution of officials in a country) were selected for New York postings from high- corruption countries. We have no rigorous statistical test to explore this possibility, but we feel that it is unlikely to be of first-order importance for
  • 217. several reasons. First, UN mission staff are selected along a range of common characteristics, including English language skills, education, and diplomatic experience, and this reduces the gap between diplomats in terms of their personal attributes. Further, we are not concerned with dif- ferential selection of “corrupt” types into the government bureaucracy vs. the private sector across countries, since we are interested in the behavior of actual government civil servants, such as the UN mission diplomats we observe. This content downloaded from 164.107.70.42 on Wed, 25 Mar 2015 17:53:25 PM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp 1046 journal of political economy in Argentina. Unfortunately, our context does not accommodate this analysis. Understanding better how corruption norms evolve is likely to be critical for the success of anticorruption reforms such as those cur- rently widely advocated by the World Bank and other foreign aid donors. Data Appendix A. New York City Diplomatic Parking Violation Data The New York City Department of Finance supplied listings of
  • 218. all unpaid parking violations of UN missions. The violations covered the period from November 24, 1997, to November 21, 2005. In order to appear in the database, a violation had to go unpaid for at least 100 days. Data were at the level of the violation and included the following entries for each violation: • Summons: unique identification number for the violation • License plate number of the violating car • The person to whom the violating car was registered, often the mission itself • Time of violation: included both hour and minute as well as calendar date • Type of violation, e.g., expired meter, fire hydrant • Street address of violation • Initial dollar value of fine issued • Additional dollar penalty for not having paid the fine on time • Amount paid toward the fine, generally zero • Name of country to which the car is registered Data on UN diplomats’ paid parking violations (violations that did not go into arrears) were made available to us in aggregate form by the New York City Department of Finance. B. UN Blue Books The United Nations issues its list of mission personnel, or Blue Book, twice yearly. We utilize edition numbers 278 (January 1997) through 294 (October
  • 219. 2005). Documents were retrieved from the UN Official Document System, avail- able at http://documents.un.org/advance.asp. Searching for the symbol ST/ SG/SER.A/### with truncation turned off returns the relevant Blue Book (where ### is the Blue Book edition number). Edition 280 (May 1998) was checked by hand to count the mission staff and spouses for each country in the Blue Book, producing the following variables: • Mission: indicator variable indicating whether the country had a UN mission • Staff: simple count of staff (staff members are always listed with their sur- names in bold) To create the longitudinal data set of diplomat parking violations, the Blue Book data were first converted into filtered html format. A program was used to parse the name and country of each diplomat in each Blue Book. Next, diplomat names from the Blue Books were matched to the parking violation data. A name was considered to have “matched” if the country, last name, and first four letters of the first name corresponded across data sets. There was some This content downloaded from 164.107.70.42 on Wed, 25 Mar 2015 17:53:25 PM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
  • 220. http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp corruption, norms, and legal enforcement 1047 manual double-checking of apparent spelling typos and duplicate or otherwise confusing names. Diplomats are considered “present” in New York City in the analysis for the months after their first appearance in a Blue Book and before the first Blue Book in which they no longer appear. Since Blue Books are pro- duced only sporadically, in months between a final Blue Book appearance and the first “nonappearance,” we assume arbitrarily that diplomats left New York at the midpoint in time between these months. C. Diplomatic Vehicles Data were provided by Murray Smith, Deputy Director at the U.S. State De- partment’s Office of Foreign Missions in April 2006. These data report counts of the number of vehicles with diplomatic license plates registered to each mission in early 2006. References Agence France–Presse. 2005. “Speedy Diplomats Steer Clear of Fines in France.” March 16.
  • 221. BBC News. 1998. “So What Are Diplomats Immune To?” October 28. http:// news.bbc.co.uk/1/hi/special_report/1998/10/98/e- cyclopedia/196677.stm. Becker, Gary S. 1968. “Crime and Punishment: An Economic Approach.” J.P.E. 76 (March/April): 169–217. Borjas, George J. 2000. “The Economic Progress of Immigrants.” In Issues in the Economics of Immigration, edited by George J. Borjas. Chicago: Univ. Chicago Press (for NBER). Di Tella, Rafael, and Ernesto Schargrodsky. 2003. “The Role of Wages and Au- diting during a Crackdown on Corruption in the City of Buenos Aires.” J. Law and Econ. 46 (April): 269–92. Fernandez, Raquel, and Alessandra Fogli. 2006. “Fertility: The Role of Culture and Family Experience.” J. European Econ. Assoc. 4 (April– May): 552–61. Fisman, Raymond, and Edward Miguel. 2006. “Cultures of Corruption: Evidence from Diplomatic Parking Tickets.” Working Paper no. 12312 (June), NBER, Cambridge, MA. Fries, Jacob H. 2002. “U.S. Revokes License Plates Issued to 185 at 30 Consulates.” New York Times, September 7.
  • 222. Ichino, Andrea, and Giovanni Maggi. 2000. “Work Environment and Individual Background: Explaining Regional Shirking Differentials in a Large Italian Firm.” Q.J.E. 115 (August): 1057–90. Kaufmann, Daniel, Aart Kraay, and Massimo Mastruzzi. 2005. “Governance Mat- ters IV: Governance Indicators for 1996–2004.” Policy Research Working Paper no. 3630, World Bank, Washington, DC. Korea Times. 1999. “Illegal Parking by Diplomats on Rise.” November 1. Kuziemko, Ilyana, and Eric Werker. 2006. “How Much Is a Seat on the Security Council Worth? Foreign Aid and Bribery at the United Nations.” J.P.E. 114 (October): 905–30. Lambsdorff, Johann Graf. 2006. “Causes and Consequences of Corruption: What Do We Know from a Cross-Section of Countries?” In International Handbook on the Economics of Corruption, edited by Susan Rose- Ackerman. Northampton, MA: Elgar. Ledyard, John O. 1995. “Public Goods: A Survey of Experimental Research.” In This content downloaded from 164.107.70.42 on Wed, 25 Mar 2015 17:53:25 PM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
  • 223. http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp 1048 journal of political economy The Handbook of Experimental Economics, edited by John H. Kagel and Alvin E. Roth. Princeton, NJ: Princeton Univ. Press. Levitt, Steven D. 1997. “Using Electoral Cycles in Police Hiring to Estimate the Effect of Police on Crime.” A.E.R. 87 (June): 270–90. ———. 2004. “Understanding Why Crime Fell in the 1990s: Four Factors That Explain the Decline and Six That Do Not.” J. Econ. Perspectives 18 (Winter): 163–90. ———. 2006. “An Economist Sells Bagels: A Case Study in Profit Maximization.” Working Paper no. 12152 (April), NBER, Cambridge, MA. Mauro, Paolo. 2004. “The Persistence of Corruption and Slow Economic Growth.” IMF Staff Papers 51 (1): 1–18. Mayer, Thierry, and Soledad Zignago. 2005. “Market Access in Global and Re- gional Trade.” Working Paper no. 2005-02 (January), Centre d’Etudes Pros- pectives et d’Informations Internationales, Paris. Olken, Benjamin A. 2006. “Corruption Perceptions vs. Corruption Reality.” Man- uscript, Harvard Univ.
  • 224. Reinikka, Ritva, and Jakob Svensson. 2004. “Local Capture: Evidence from a Central Government Transfer Program in Uganda.” Q.J.E. 119 (May): 679– 705. Rockwell, John. 2004. “Reverberations: Where Mimes Patrolled the Streets and the Mayor Was Superman.” New York Times, July 9. Schiavo-Campo, Salvatore, Giulio de Tommaso, and Amit Mukherjee. 1999. “An International Statistical Survey of Government Employment and Wages.” Pol- icy Research Working Paper no. 1806, World Bank, Washington, DC. Singleton, Don. 2004. “Bill Socks Scofflaw Diplos.” New York Daily News, November 21, p. 28. Steinhauer, Jennifer. 2002. “Suspension of Hostilities over Diplomats’ Tickets.” New York Times, August 23. Tirole, Jean. 1996. “A Theory of Collective Reputations (with Applications to the Persistence of Corruption and to Firm Quality).” Rev. Econ. Studies 63 (January): 1–22. Witzel, Morgen. 2005. “How to Respond When Only Bribe Money Talks.” Fi- nancial Times, July 11, London ed. 1, p. 14.
  • 225. This content downloaded from 164.107.70.42 on Wed, 25 Mar 2015 17:53:25 PM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp