SlideShare a Scribd company logo
1 of 94
n
R E E 693 5
T o c o m p l e t e th i s e x a m y o u n e e d t o a n s w e r 8 q u
e s t i o n l i s t e d b e lo w . T h e
f i r s t t w o q u e s t i o n s a r e t o b e a n s w e r e d i n E x c
e l u s i n g th e a s s o c ia t e d t a b s
i n c l u d e d o n t h e e x a m R E E 6935 t h a t i s p r o v i d e
d t o y o u q u e s t i o n 3
- 8 a r e
t o b e a n s w e r e d o n a Wo r d D o c u m e n t i n t h e o r d
e r i n w h ic h t h e y a p p e a r .
D u e A p r i l 28 , 2015 .
1. ) (9 P o i n t s ) U s i n g t h e d a t a p r o v i d e d t o y o u i
n t h e P r o b l e m 1 t a b ,
c a lc u la t e t h e r e q u e s t e d v a l u e s a n d i n c l u d e y
o u r a n s w e r i n th e i r
r e s p e c t i v e c e l ls h i gh l ig h t e d i n y e l lo w .
2 . ) (10 P o i n t ) T h e t a b la b e l e d P r o b l e m 2 i n c l u
d e s m o n t h ly p r i c e d a t a o n
th e SA P 500 (SPY ) a s w e l l a s o n K B H o m e (K B H , a r
e a l e s t a t e
d e v e lo p m e n t c o m p a n y ) a n d o n H o m e P r o p e r t
i e s I n c . (H M E , a n d e q u i t y
R E I T s p e c ia l i z e s i n a p a r tm e n t r e n t a ls ) . U s i
n g r e g r e s s i o n c a l c u l a t e t h e
B e t a o f e a c h o f t h e s e 2 r e a l e s t a t e c o m p a n ie s
f o r t h e f u l l t im e p e r i o d
p r o v id e d t o y o u .
a . D is p l a y y o u r c a l c u l a t e d B e t a s i n t h e c e ll s
h i g h l igh t e d i n y e l l o w .
Y o u m a y i n c l u d e y o u r f u l l r e g r e s s i o n r e s u l t
s i n t w o o th e r s e p a r a t e
t a b s
b . W h i c h c o m p a n y h a s a h i g h e r B e t a ? I n o n e t
o tw o s e n t e n c e s
e x p l a i n w h y y o u d id o r d i d n
'
t e x p e c t t h a t c o m p a n y t o b e
a s s o c ia t e d w i t h a h ig h e r B e t a .
3 . (10 P o i n t s ) P l e a s e r e f e r t o t h e p a p e r t it l e d
O n t h e R e la t i o n b e t w e e n
L o c a l A m e n i t ie s a n d H o u s i n g P r ic e C h a n g e s
"
p r o v i d e d t o y o u w i t h t h i s
e x a m a n d a n s w e r t h e f o l lo w i n g q u e s t io n s .
a . B r i e f ly e x p l a i n w h a t w e c a n l e a r n f r o m F ig
u r e 2 ? A r e t h e s e
r e s u l t s e x p e c t e d ? Wh y ?
b . B r i e f ly e x p l a i n w h a t w e c a n l e a r n f r o m f i g
u r e 4? A r e t h e s e r e s u l t s
e x p e c t e d ? W hy ?
c . B r i e f ly e x p l a i n w h a t w e c a n l e a r n f r o m t h e
r e g r e s s i o n r e s u l t s
p r e s e n t e d i n c o l u m n (4) o f t a b l e 4 . H o w t h e s e
r e s u lt s a r e d if f e r e n t
f r o m t h e r e s u l t s p r e s e n t e d i n c o l u m n (2) o f t a
b le 4?
d . B r i e f l y e x p l a i n w h a t w e c a n l e a r n f r o m t a b
l e 6 t h a t w e d o n
'
t
a l r e a d y k n o w f r o m t h e r e s u l t s p r e s e n t e d i n t
h e p r e v i o u s t a b l e s .
NEATPAGEINFO:id=C46A481D-C837-496A-BF88-
1036B1B658D9
NEATPAGEINFO:id=1C69E900-548F-4525-A8FC-
241D36019B8E
NEATPAGEINFO:id=FFE7D9CB-237F-4EF0-A0CE-
1E8CE4F89D7D
NEATPAGEINFO:id=D3925A9E-2F11-486E-BE0D-
F7BAD671A14E
On the Relation between Local Amenities and Housing Price
Changes
Eli Beracha, Ph.D.
Hollo School of Real Estate, Florida International University
Benjamin T. Gilbert, Ph.D.
Department of Economics and Finance, University of Wyoming
Tyler Kjorstad
Department of Economics and Finance, University of Wyoming
Kiplan S. Womack, Ph.D.
Belk College of Business, UNC Charlotte
Abstract
This paper explores the extent to which local amenities are
related to housing price volatility and
appreciation in different US cities. Using total amenity values
constructed by Albouy (2009), we
find that cities with higher amenity values experience greater
housing price appreciation along
with higher price volatility. These empirical results are inline
with the land leverage hypothesis
presented by Bostic, et al. (2007) and are also supported by our
theoretical model, which shows
that variations in long run anticipated income affect
households’ willingness to pay for the physical
attributes as well as amenities of housing. Our results are shown
to be symmetrical across up and
down markets and are robust to a series of robustness tests, such
as regional and land supply
elasticity controls.
Keywords: house prices, volatility, amenities, land leverage
JEL codes: R00, R14, R21, R31
Introduction
Over the last few decades housing rate of price appreciation
and price volatility varied in a
material way across different locations. Housing is not only the
largest single asset held by most
American households1, but also represent a concentrated,
levered and undiversified financial
exposure for many of them. Moreover, housing value and
volatility play an increasingly important
role in the performance of a progressively integrated broad
economy, as it was most evident during
the housing boom of the early 2000’s and the “great recession”
that followed. Therefore, exploring
factors that may explain variations in housing value is
warranted.
This paper examines the extent to which housing price
volatility and rate of appreciation
are related to the local amenities that accompany the physical
characteristics of housing in a large
sample of US locations. At any given location land and its
associated amenities is limited in supply
and non-reproducible. In contrast, improvements can be
reproduced in greater supply elsewhere
and experience physical and functional obsolescence over time.
This implies that supply and
demand shocks in the local economy are expected to be
capitalized into land values, not the
structure. As a result, higher housing price volatility is
predicted in areas where the value of
locational amenities is high and these areas should also
appreciate at a faster pace in an overall
growing economy. This line of reasoning is similar to the land
leverage hypothesis that is presented
by Bostic, Longhofer and Redfearn (2007) and investigated in
the recent literature.
Evidence from our empirical analysis show a positive and
robust relation between housing
price volatility and amenity value. Additionally, a positive
relation that is statistically and
economically significant between housing price appreciation
and amenities is also illustrated.
However, when the relation between risk-adjusted price
appreciation and amenities is examined,
1 Based on U.S. Census Bureau, Survey of Income and Program
Participation
the results are dependent on whether risk-adjusted price
appreciation is measured in absolute terms
or relative to the performance of the general housing market.
Overall, the empirical results of our
analysis support our theoretical model and hypotheses.
We takes advantage of a set of three land value proxies, namely
Quality of Life, Trade-
Productivity and Total Amenity values, in order to provide
evidence on the relation between land
values and changes in housing prices for a broad sample of
cities. Our paper makes several
contributions to the existing literature. First, we show that the
value of amenities can proxy for the
value of land share, which is difficult to estimate mainly due to
data availability. Amenity value
and land share are also shown to have similar relation with
supply constraints that the literature
finds to be important when determining real estate price
movements and trends (Glaeser, Gyourko
and Saiz (2008), for example). Second, for a large sample of
cities we provide evidence of positive
relation not only between amenities and housing price volatility,
but also between amenities and
housing price appreciation. To our knowledge, our study is the
first attempt to explore both of
these links. Moreover, we provide evidence on the relation
between amenities and risk-adjusted
housing appreciation in absolute and relative terms. Third, and
lastly, we are the first to document
symmetry in the relation between amenities and housing price
performance in up and down
markets as well as the robustness of this relation to supply
constraints and other locational controls.
We believe that our paper enhances the understanding of how
local amenities are relate to
changes in housing values. A better understanding of this
relation is an important issue, not just
for the individual home owner, but also for investors, lenders,
and tax collectors and hence may
also have policy implications.
Literature Review
Developed streams of literature explore the relation between
specific local amenities (or
disamenities) and housing prices. Examples of housing related
amenities investigated in these
studies include school quality (Black (1999) and Bogart and
Cromwell (2000), among many
others), proximity to the ocean and ocean view (Landry and
Hindsley (2011) and Wyman,
Hutchinson and Tiwari (2014), for example), susceptibility to
flood hazard (Turnbullm, Zahirovic-
Hebert and Mothorpe (2013)), and many more. Because these
studies predominantly focus on a
the effect of a specific amenity on housing values at the local
level they are not directly relate to
our study, which examines the relation between a broad set of
amenities on housing performance
a across different cities and regions.
The stream of literature that is most closely related to our
research includes papers that
explore land values and study the land leverage hypothesis.
Davis and Palumbo (2007) construct
a database that distinguishes between the value of residential
land and structures for 46 large US
metropolitan areas. The authors report that the average value of
land relative to the value of
structures experienced a material increase over the 1984 – 2004
time period, which implies that
future rate of housing price appreciation and volatility are
likely to increasingly be determined by
demand factors. In their paper, the authors find substantial
regional variation in land share. In 2004,
land share was estimated to comprise 74% of value for homes in
the West Coast, which is more
than double the Midwest share of 36%. Similarly, Albouy and
Ehrlich (2012) find that land share
varies from 11% to 48% with a national average of 37%.2 In
regards to appreciation, nationally
2 The estimates from Davis and Palumbo (2007) are based on a
residual method (difference between total property
value and the estimated value of the structure) whereas the
estimates from Albouy and Ehrlich (2012) are transaction-
based from land sales across the U.S. The latter study points out
that their estimates are generally lower than that of
the former study and that this is likely due to the
methodological differences. In a later study Albouy and Ehrlich
(2013) analyze land values from transactions across the U.S.
and find that the strongest predictor of value per acre is
lot size, followed by location, and then time.
from 1984 to 2004. Davis and Palumbo (2007) estimate that
land appreciated 204% while the
structure appreciated 19%. This level of land appreciation is
consistent with the estimates from the
national-level transaction based land price index of Sirmans and
Slade (2012) and the MSA-level
transaction based land price index of Nichols, Oliner and
Mulhall (2013). Bostic, Longhofer and
Redfearn (2006) investigate the relationship between land
leverage and land taxation regimes. The
study finds that the growth in land values is more volatile than
growth in overall property value,
which means that higher land leveraged metropolitan areas have
higher overall property value
growth volatility.3 In an earlier study, Dolde and Tirtiroglu
(2002) investigate volatility shifts in
regional house price changes and find that the vast majority of
“volatility events” are purely
regional, rather than national, in nature. Similarly, Miao,
Ramchander and Simpson (2011) find
linkages of returns and volatility within geographic regions.
On a more local level, Bostic, Longhofer and Redfearn (2007)
refer to the land leverage
hypothesis when examine prices of land and improvement in
Wichita, Kansas. Bostic Longhofer
and Refearn highlights the importance of this property price
decomposition for better
understanding of prices of the real estate markets. Paciorek
(2013) examines the relation between
housing volatility and regulation of new housing supply.
Paciorek illustrate how more regulation
lowers the elasticity of new housing supply by increasing the
lags in the permit process and adding
to the cost of supplying new houses on the margin. These
regulations anlong with geographic
limitations lead to less investment, on average. Paciorek then
links his findings to illustrate that
stricter regulation combined with geographic limitations
decrease the responsiveness of
investment to demand shocks and hence amplify volatility in
property prices. Kok, Monkkonen
and Quigley (2014) also examined the effect of local land use
regulations and find that they are
3 Haurin and Zhou (2010) provide an excellent summary of the
determinants of house price volatility.
closely linked to the value of houses sold. Focusing on the San
Francisco Bay Area, the authors
find this link to be particularly strong because regulations in
that area are so pervasive and land
values represent a large fraction of house values.
Theory and Hypothesis Development
In this section we develop hypotheses about the relationship
between local amenities and
home price volatility. We use a standard hedonic price model to
derive predictions about volatility
and risk-adjusted returns that arise from variation in
macroeconomic fundamentals that might alter
a household’s expectations of permanent income. Specifically,
we show that (1) home price
volatility is unambiguously greater in housing markets with
more amenities, and (2) amenities
have a theoretically ambiguous effect on risk-adjusted returns
because of the tradeoff between the
capitalization of growing amenity values in home prices as
incomes rise, and the unambiguous
increase in volatility due to amenities.
Consider a typical formulation of the hedonic price equation:
����� = �0� + ∑ ��� ����
�
�=1
+ ��� �� + ���
(I)
where ����� is the natural log of home prices in market i at
time t, ���� are a set of J home
characteristics (e.g., square footage, lot size, etc.) and �� is
the level of amenities that homebuyers
have access to in that market. This can be considered, for
example, an approximation to the locus
of bid-ask tangency points in price-attribute space as shown by
Rosen (1974) where ��� captures
approximation error and other iid unobserved local shocks to
prices. The value of home
characteristics in a market may vary over time to capture trends
in physical property improvements
or changes in valuation of those characteristics because of
income or preferences, The level of
amenities captures more stable variables like proximity to
coastline and average climate and is
therefore fixed. Notice, however, that we allow the coefficients
to vary with time, which is a natural
way to allow the contribution of each attribute in overall price
to depend on time-varying
macroeconomic conditions. In order to decompose the overall
price volatility into a home-value
component and an amenity component, define ��� as the
“base” price based on home
characteristics only:
����� = �0� + ∑ ��� ����
�
�=1
Consider the following process for base home price
appreciation:
����� = ����,�−1 + �� + ��� , ��� ~���(0,
��
2 )
Here we allow base home prices to grow at a stable average
growth rate �� reflecting long-run
macroeconomic or permanent income growth, subject to
idiosyncratic short-run macroeconomic
shocks ��� . For simplicity, we restrict growth rates to be
equal across local markets. Allowing
market-specific growth by explicitly specifying processes for
�0� , ��� , and ���� comes at the
expense of unnecessary algebraic complexity without changing
the qualitative results or providing
any additional understanding of the intuition. In the present
formulation, temporal variation in real
estate prices is driven by purely macroeconomic changes. This
allows us to isolate the relationship
of amenities with price volatility.
We can now rewrite (I) as the sum of the logged base price and
the contribution of
amenities:
����� = ����� + ��� �� + ��� (I’)
In this formulation, ��� is a semi-elasticity which captures
the percentage difference in a home’s
value due to a difference in the level of local amenities. We
consider two cases for the ��� process:
Case A: ��� = �� + ��� , ��� ~���(0, ��
2). (IIA)
Case B: ��� = �� + ��,�−1 + ��� , ��� ~���(0, ��
2). (IIB)
In Case A, we give this parameter a stationary distribution to
capture the possibility that the
proportional contribution of a local amenity to a home’s value
is high during positive
macroeconomic shocks and vice versa, and varies around a fixed
mean. In Case B, we consider
the case in which the amenity contribution increases as
permanent incomes increase with economic
growth. This second case implies that not only home prices, but
home price appreciation is greater
in areas with more amenities.
The vector of annual shocks to base home values and amenity
values � = (��� , ��� )
� has
the (2X2) covariance matrix �:
� = [
��
2 ���
��� ��
2
]
Where ��� > 0 captures the possibility that both sources of
temporal home price variation are
driven by common macroeconomic or housing market shocks.
Subtracting ����,�−1 from �����, it is straightforward to
obtain
��
���
��,�−1
= ��
���
��,�−1
+ (��� − ��,�−1)�� + (��� − ��,�−1)
which we can rewrite as
���� = ��� + ��� �� + ��� (III)
where ���� is the growth in actual home prices in market i
and ��� is the growth in base home
prices between periods t-1 and t. We can show the effects of
amenities on volatility and risk-
adjusted returns using either the straightforward calculation of
volatility and the Sharpe Ratio, or
by specifying a capital asset pricing model (CAPM) for
residential real estate and examining the
asset Beta (�) and Jensen’s Alpha (�) for market i relative to
the U.S. housing price index.
The Effect of Amenities on Home Price Volatility
Taking the expectation of (III) in the two cases gives,
Case A: �(���� ) = �� (IVA)
Case B: �(����) = �� + ���� (IVB)
which will be used in the calculation of both volatility and the
Beta (�) for market i, and in the
derivation of risk-adjusted returns. Taking the square root of the
variance of (III) will provide an
expression for how home price volatility is affected by the level
of amenities. This expression is
given by
Case A:
√���(����) = ��� = √��
2 + 2��
2�A
2 + 2�� ��� + 2��
2
(VA)
Case B:
√���(���� ) = ��� = √��
2 + ��
2�A
2 + 2�� ��� + 2��
2
(VB)
In both cases this will be an unambiguously positive function of
amenities as long as the home-
attribute valuation and amenity valuation drivers do not
systematically move in opposite
directions. This is unlikely because these drivers are common
macroeconomic shocks, so the
covariance term under the radical will be nonnegative.
The CAPM for residential real estate, explained in more detail
in the Methodology section,
can be thought of as a regression of housing price growth in an
individual market on growth in the
U.S. Housing Price Index, as in
���� = �� + �� ��� + ���
Where ��� is the growth in the U.S. Housing Price Index, and
��� is a mean-zero regression error.
Because ��� is the growth in an index that summarizes
prices across all markets, we can write it
as
��� = ��� + Δ��� �̅� + Δ��̅�
The Beta for housing assets in market i is simply �� =
���(����,���)
���(���)
, which in the two cases reduces
to:
Case A:
�� =
��
2 + �̅���� + �� (��� + 2�̅���
2)
��
2 + 2�̅���� + 2�̅�
2 ��
2
(VIA)
Case B:
�� =
��
2 + �̅���� + �� (��� + �̅���
2)
��
2 + 2�̅���� + �̅�
2��
2
(VIB)
In either case, once again this is an unambiguously increasing
function of amenities in
market i. Hence, we hypothesize the following:
H1: All other things equal, the magnitude of real estate price
fluctuations (volatility) in a
particular location and the amenity value associate with that
location are positively related.
The Effect of Amenities on Risk-Adjusted Returns
Next we consider whether we should expect residential property
investors to be
compensated with greater risk-adjusted returns for the
additional risks posed by the increased
volatility, or whether we should expect homebuyers to accept
additional risk for a given return in
order to enjoy the amenity. We first evaluate this question using
the Sharpe Ratio, followed by an
examination of Jensen’s Alpha from the CAPM model. In our
context the Sharpe Ratio can be
written as
��� =
�(����)
���
(VI)
We have already seen that ��� is an increasing function of
amenities, and now we must show
whether expected price growth is increasing in amenities by
enough to offset the denominator.
From (IVA), we know that in Case A the numerator of the
Sharpe Ratio does not depend on
amenities. Therefore, in this case risk-adjusted returns decline
with amenities. This is intuitive for
Case A because although amenities are a component of price
levels, they do not contribute to home
price appreciation and only add volatility to the behavior of
prices over time.
As we will show in the empirical section, however, U.S. home
price appreciation is
significantly positively related to amenities, suggesting that
Case B may be more relevant
empirically. We can see from (IVB) that home price
appreciation and price levels increase with
amenity levels. The question is now whether the effect of �� in
appreciation outweighs the
increased volatility in calculation of risk-adjusted returns.
Using the chain rule,
���
���
=
����� −
1
2
��� (2�� ��
2 + ��� )
���
2
(VII)
The sign of this expression hinges on a mean-variance tradeoff
in the amenity contribution to the
overall home price process. It can be shown using (VB) and
(VI) that the sign is more likely to be
positive when �� is large relative to ��, ��
2 is relatively small, and ��
2 is relatively large. In other
words, if the amenity contribution to price growth has a low
variance but a high mean relative to
the appreciation in base prices, then risk-adjusted returns are
more likely to be higher in markets
with high amenities. Likewise, if base home price appreciation
has relatively low variance, adding
additional volatility from amenities without much additional
price appreciation to accompany it
can drive down risk-adjusted returns.
A similar mean-variance tradeoff arises in Jensen’s Alpha,
although because Jensen’s
Alpha for a single market is measured relative to the broader
U.S. residential real estate market,
whereas the Sharpe Ratio is an absolute measure, the two
quantities need not produce the same
outcome. In our context Jensen’s Alpha is defined as
�� = �(���� ) − �� �(��� )
In Case A, this collapses to �� = (1 − �� )��, which is
unambiguously decreasing in amenities as
�� increases in amenities, again because in Case A amenities
do not affect raw home price returns.
In Case B, amenities contribute to housing price appreciation
directly in addition to adding
to volatility. This a tradeoff in Jensen’s Alpha is
�� = �� + ���� − �� (�� + ���̅�)
Taking the derivative with respect to �� and simplifying
yields
���
���
=
��(��
2 + �̅���� ) − �� (��� + �̅���
2)
��
2 + 2�̅���� + �̅�
2��
2
(VIII)
Similar to the Sharpe Ratio, equation (VIII) shows that if
amenities make a low-mean and high-
variance contribution to price appreciation, relative to the mean
and variance of base price
appreciation, then risk adjusted returns will be lower in cities
with high amenity values (and vice
versa). Unlike the Sharpe Ratio, however, because Alpha is a
relative measure, the sign of (VIII)
also depends on the broader U.S. market average amenity
contribution to growth �̅�. In particular,
if �̅� is relatively large then the volatility of amenity values
��
2 has a bigger negative effect on
returns in market i relative to the broader market. In other
words, if amenities are a large share of
overall market growth (rather than in just a few individual
markets), then volatility in amenity
values take a bigger toll on risk-adjusted returns. In the
remainder of the paper we evaluate each
of these relationships empirically.
Data
We construct the dataset analyzed in this paper from a few
different sources. The dependent
variable in this study is a measure of housing price volatility in
different Metropolitan Statistical
Areas (MSAs) across the US. This variable is calculated (as we
describe in the methodology
section) from the series of Housing Price Index (HPI) that are
published by the Federal Housing
Finance Agency (FHFA). The FHFA publishes an HPI for just
over 400 MSAs with quarterly
frequency beginning as early as the first quarter of 1975 for
some MSAs. We take advantage of
the length of these series and examine the Q1 1975 through Q3
2013 time period in this study. The
HPI for each MSA is also used in order to calculate the rate of
housing appreciation and
segmentation of the data into up and down pricing trend
periods.
Our main independent variables of interest are the values
associated with the
metropolitans’ total amenity value, which are extracted from
Albouy (2009). In Albouy (2009) the
author also estimates values for the quality of life and trade-
productivity, which are included in
the estimation of the total amenity values. Albouy estimates
these values for 241 MSAs across the
US.4 Table 1 reports these values for the top and bottom five
metro areas in terms of total amenities,
quality of life and trade productivity in order to give the reader
a sense for these values.5 The San
Francisco-Oakland-San Jose MSA is topping the list with total
amenity value of 0.323 while
McAllen-Edinburg-Mission is at the bottom of the list with a
total amenity value of -0.225.
Additionally, Table 1 shows that MSAs with high amenity value
are also associate with high trade-
productivity and quality of life values and vice versa. This is
not surprising given that Albouy
constructs the total amenity value from the trade-productivity
and quality of life values. Because
our study focuses on the relation between housing price
volatility and amenity values rather than
the establishment of these values, we employs Albouy’s
estimates at their face value without
making an attempt to improve, change or challenge them. For
brevity, we also don’t discuss the
4 Glaser, Saiz and Summers (2008) use amenity variables
(individual measures, not index-based) to control for housing
demand in models of house price appreciation and construction
permits. The authors note that while these variables
don’t change over time, demand for them might have, so they
provide a natural way of controlling for changes in
demand.
5 A full list of the 241 metropolitans and their respective
amenity, trade-productivity and quality of life values can be
found in Albouy (2009).
methodology used in Albouy (2009) to estimate these values
and interested readers are encouraged
to refer to the original paper.
Albouy (2009) notes that other directly observed variables that
are used in the literature in
order to characterize and distinguish between different locations
are associated with overall
amenity value. Therefore, we make an effort to collect some of
the commonly used area
characteristics to determine whether Albouy’s estimates are
superior proxies when explaining
housing price volatilities. These area characteristics include
land supply elasticity, education,
weather and proximity to recreational water.
A widely used measure for land availability is the land supply
elasticity (LSE) measure by
Albert Saiz. Originally, Saiz (2010) published LSE estimates
for 95 large US cities, but since then
Saiz expanded the availability of the estimates to 269 US
cities.6 These values range between 0.60
and 12.14 for Miami, FL where available land is scarce and for
Pine Bluff, AR where available
land is plentiful, respectively. Since Saiz’s measures are
available at the city rather than the MSA
level, we use a weighted average that is based on cities
population to construct a LSE value for the
MSAs in our sample. We refer to the United States Census
Bureau for statistics on cities’
population and record the 2010 population estimate for each
city in our dataset.
Values for cities’ education level are also extracted from the
Census Bureau and are based
on 5-year estimates of the American Community Survey.
Specifically, we use the percentage of
the population over the age of 25 with a Bachelor degree or
higher as our education proxy. Increase
in the supply of college graduates increases local wages directly
and indirectly via a spillover effect
6 Glaeser and Gyourko (2003), Glaeser, Gyourko and Saks
(2005), Saiz (2010), Paciorek (2013), and Kok, Monkkonen
and Quigley (2014) collectively find that inelastic land supply
and zoning restrictions and regulation (measured as
lags in the permit process, increasing the number of permit
reviews) in urban areas amplify house price volatility by
creating scarcity, increasing the time to develop and adding
costs of supplying new houses. Grimes and Aitken (2010)
show that this effect is not domestic in nature when exploring
housing price dynamics in New Zealand.
that impacts the wages of local non-college graduates (Moretti
(2004) and Rosenthal and Strange
(2008), for example). For general weather information we first
refer to the National Oceanic
Atmospheric as a source7 from which we gather the value for
the average percentage of sunshine
per day in each city included in our database. Unfortunately, the
NOAA only provides estimates
of this value for 115 of the 238 MSAs in our sample. As
alternative weather proxies that are
available for more MSAs we use the annual precipitation in
inches and a heating- and cooling-
degree-days measure, which reflects the variability in
temperatures from a defined base8. For these
values we refer to Weather Base and Weather Data Depot,
respectively, which compile these
measures from the National Climatic Data Center. Finally, we
create an ocean or Great Lakes
dummy indicator that equals to 1 if a city is located within 70
or 40 miles distance from a shore of
an ocean or one of the Great Lakes, respectively. Table 2
provides summary statistics of the MSAs’
characteristics included in our dataset.
Table 3 reports the Spearman and Pearson correlation
coefficients between the land share
values employed in Davis and Palumbo (2007), Saiz’s supply
elasticity values and the amenities
values used in this study as well as their components (quality of
life and trade productivity). The
land share values are only available for 46 cities, which is
relatively small subset of the 241 cities
for which we have amenity, quality and productivity values.9
The correlations between the Land
Share and Amenities values are high (80% and 83.7% for the
Spearman and Pearson, respectively)
and statistically significant. The correlations between the Land
Share values and each of the
components of the Amenities values independently, while
somewhat lower, is still high and
7 NOAA satellites and information Comparative Climate Data:
http://ols.nndc.noaa.gov/plolstore/plsql/olstore.prodspecific
8 Heating and cooling degree days are calculated using the year
2010 and 60 degree Fahrenheit as the base.
9 We use the time series average land share value for each of
the 46 cities in order to calculate these correlation. The
average land share value is based on the Q4:1984 to Q1:2014
time period.
http://ols.nndc.noaa.gov/plolstore/plsql/olstore.prodspecific
statistically significant. Recognizing the high correlation
between the Land Share and Amenities
values allows us to link our results to the land leverage
hypothesis already established in the
literature. Additionally, Table 3 illustrates that the correlation
between the land share and elasticity
values is very similar to the correlation between the amenities
and elasticity values (Pearson
correlation of -0.566 vs. -0.561, for example). Given the
relevancy of the land supply elasticity to
the land value literature, these similar correlation values further
highlights the validity of amenity
values as a proxy for land share.
Methodology
Measuring Housing Price Volatility:
Two commonly used methodologies are employed in this paper
in order to measure
housing prices volatility across the MSAs included in our
sample. The first measure for price
volatility is the standard deviation of the returns associated with
the HPI series for each of housing
prices. Our standard deviation measure is based on the inflation
adjusted returns from the HPI
series and using a 1-year (4 quarters) rolling window.
Our second approach for measuring housing price volatility
captures the sensitivity of
housing price changes in each MSA to changes in housing
prices in the broad US market. This
measure is similar to the Beta (β) often used in the finance
literature as a measure for the systematic
risk associated with individual stocks. Specifically, we regress
the quarterly returns of each MSA
in our sample (������,� ) using its HPI series on the
quarterly returns calculated from the HPI series
for the US as a whole (�����) as per equation (1):
������,� = �� + �� ������ (1)
Where the �� coefficient is the volatility measure for MSA i.
For robustness, we calculate both measures of housing price
volatility for the full time
period during which the HPI series of each MSA is available10
as well as for seven predefined sub
periods of our sample. We pre-defined these seven sub periods
based on inflation adjusted “up”
and “down” markets so that the cutoffs between these periods
are the peaks and troughs in the real
prices of the broad US housing market. Panel A of Figure 1
displays the inflation adjusted HPI
series for the US that spans the Q1 1975 to Q3 2013 time period
along with the segmentations of
the seven sub periods within. The sub periods of our sample are
the following:
1. Q1 1975 – Q1 1979 – 1st up market
2. Q2 1979 – Q3 1982 – 1st down market
3. Q4 1982 – Q3 1989 – 2nd up market
4. Q4 1989 – Q1 1995 – 2nd down market
5. Q2 1995 – Q4 2006 – 3rd up market
6. Q1 2007 – Q2 2012 – 3rd down market
7. Q3 2012 – Q3 2013 – 4th up market
The segmentation of the data into these sub periods allows us to
measure the volatility of
housing prices during “up” and “down” markets and examine
whether the correlation between the
MSAs’ housing price volatility and labor productivity or
amenity values is symmetric during
periods of general up and down housing price trends.11
Panel B of Figure 1 displays the inflation adjusted housing
price trends in two selected
MSAs for which we observed relatively high (Stockton, CA)
and relatively low (Louisville, KY)
10 While the HPI is available for the US as a whole as well as
for some MSAs from the 1st quarter of 1975, the HPI
series begins at some later date for other MSAs.
11 Given that the HPI series becomes available at a different
time for each MSA, it is possible that the beta we
calculated for MSAs for the first sub period they enters our
sample is extreme due to a short time period during which
it is calculated. To attenuate the effect of this issue on our
analysis we exclude the betas calculations for MSAs in the
sub period in which they enter our sample, if it falls within the
top or bottom 5% of our betas for that sub period.
price volatility. The purpose of this panel is to visually
highlight the variability in price volatility
across our sample of MSAs.
Housing Price Volatility and Amenities:
A regression analysis is used in order to determine the relation
between housing price
volatility and total amenity values. We begin with a simple
regression where the measured housing
price volatility for each MSA (������) is the dependent
variable (measured either in standard
deviation or with beta) and quality of life (Quality) and trade-
productivity (Productivity) or total
amenity value (Amenity) serve as the independent variables.
Because Albouy’s quality of life and
trade-productivity measures are both used in order to derive the
total amenity value (and therefore
highly correlated), we make sure that we either include the
former two measures or the later one
in our regressions, but not all three simultaneously.
������� = �0 + �1����������� +
�2���������������� (2.1)
������� = �0 + �3����������� (2.2)
We next include additional MSAs characteristics in the
regression in order examine the
extent to which Albouy’s measures are able to explain housing
price volatility above and beyond
other observed characteristics.
������� = �0 + �1����������� +
�2���������������� + ∑ ��,� ��,�
�
�=1 (3.1)
������� = �0 + �3����������� + ∑ ��,� ��,�
�
�=1 (3.2)
where X is a vector of each MSA characteristics, which includes
some or all of the following: the
natural log of the population (Population), our education
measure (Education), heating degree
days in thousands (HDD), cooling degree days in thousands
(CDD), average percentage of
sunshine (Sunshine), precipitation in inches (Precipitation), our
dummy variable for coast or the
Great Lakes (Coastal/Lakes) and Saiz’s land supply elasticity
measure (LSE).
Given the possibility that different regions within the US
include a cluster of higher or
lower volatility MSAs, we introduce regions control dummy
into our regressions. Specifically, we
use the classification for 4 regions or 9 sub regions from the
U.S. Census of Bureau.
������� = �0 + �1����������� +
�2���������������� + ∑ ��,� ��,�
�
�=1 (4.1)
������� = �0 + �3����������� + ∑ ��,� ��,�
�
�=1 (4.2)
where Y is a vector of dummies for either 3 regions or 8 sub
regions, leaving the Northeast region
or the New England sub region as the omitted variable,
respectively.
For robustness, we repeat the previous regression specifications
for up- and down-trending
housing price periods separately. This “up” and “down” market
segregation allows us to determine
whether the relation we observe between housing price
volatility and amenities exists regardless
of the general direction in which housing prices are heading or
driven by a particular housing price
trend. In order to capture housing price volatility during the up-
and down-trending periods of our
sample we calculate a volatility value for every MSA in our
sample during each trend and use
these values as the dependent variable in our regressions. To do
so, we first use our beta and
standard deviation methodologies to calculate a volatility value
for every MSA during each of our
predefined seven sub periods. We then average12 the values
from periods 1, 3, 5 and 7 and 2, 4,
and 6 to create an up- and down-trending volatility measure for
every MSA, respectively.
12 We use both simple average and a weighted average that is
based on the length of each sub period available for each
MSA. The results using these two different approaches are
qualitatively identical.
Housing Price Performance and Amenity values:
To determine the extent to which amenity values are related to
housing price appreciation
we investigate the raw real (inflation adjusted) rate of price
appreciation as well as risk-adjusted
appreciation rate. We employ the following regressions in order
to determine whether housing
appreciation is, on average, positively or negatively related to
the amenity value of the MSA in
which they are located:
������� = �0 + �1����������� +
�2���������������� + ∑ ��,� ��,�
�
�=1 (5.1)
������� = �0 + �3����������� + ∑ ��,� ��,�
�
�=1 (5.2)
where ������� is the average housing price appreciation
rate in annual real terms in MSA i over
the full sample period. We calculate housing price appreciation
in real rather than nominal terms
in order to avoid the possibility that the earlier segment of the
data, during which inflation was
higher compared with the later segment, would be
overrepresented for non-housing related
reasons.
To examine the relation between MSA amenity values and the
risk-adjusted price
appreciation of housing, we employ two measures of risk-
adjusted return. The first measure is the
alpha estimation for each MSA from equation (1). This risk-
adjusted measure is analogous to the
Jensen Alpha that is commonly used as the risk-adjusted return
for individual securities in the
finance literature. The alpha estimations are then regressed on
the amenity variables.
�� = �0 + �1����������� +
�2���������������� + ∑ ��,� ��,�
�
�=1 (6.1)
�� = �0 + �3����������� + ∑ ��,� ��,�
�
�=1 (6.2)
The second risk-adjusted price appreciation measure is the ratio
between the standard deviation of
housing price appreciation and housing price appreciation for
each MSA in our sample. This
measure resembles the Sharpe ratio that is commonly used in
the finance literature. Similar to
equation (6) we regress the Sharpe ratio of each MSA (���)
on the amenity variables.
��� = �0 + �1����������� +
�2���������������� + ∑ ��,� ��,�
�
�=1 (7.1)
��� = �0 + �3����������� + ∑ ��,� ��,�
�
�=1 (7.2)
It is important to note that while Jensen alpha and Sharpe ratio
are both valid and widely
acceptable risk-adjusted return measures, they are
fundamentally different. Jensen alpha captures
the excess return of each MSA while taking into consideration
the risk associated with each MSA
relative to the overall market. On the other hand, the Sharpe
ratio is an absolute measure, which
isn’t calculated with respect the overall market. Hence, it is
possible that the regression coefficients
from equations (6) and (7) would not carry a consistent sign.
Results
Volatility and Amenities
Table 4 reports the results from regression specifications (2)
and (3). The standard
deviation volatility measure is the dependent variable in
columns (1) through (4) and the beta
volatility measure is the dependent variable in columns (5)
through (8). The positive and
statistically significant coefficients of the Quality and
Productivity variables in column (1) indicate
that housing price volatility is higher in areas associated with
higher quality of life or trade-
productivity. Similarly, the positive statistically significant
coefficient of the Amenity variable in
column (2) indicates that areas with higher amenity value
experience higher price volatility.
Columns (3) and (4) provide additional evidence that the
positive relations between volatility and
the measures for Quality, Productivity and Amenity remain
statistically significant even after
controlling for a few directly observed area characteristics that
would signal about the desirability
of each location and its land supply constraints. These directly
observed characteristics provide
additional explanatory power to the regressions and enhance the
adjusted R^2 values from about
36% to 63%.
The results reported in columns (5) through (8) are qualitative
similar to the results
observed in columns (1) through (4). The similarity in the
results suggests that the method of
measuring housing price volatility does not play a major rule
when the relation between level of
volatility and the amenities is gauged. The signs of the
additional directly observed characteristics
also remain stable across the different specification. However,
it appears that the adjusted R^2 in
the regressions that employ Beta as a volatility measure is
somewhat lower than the regressions
that use standard deviation as a volatility measure. Panels A and
B of Figure 2 visually illustrate
the relationship between housing volatility measured either by
standard deviation (Panel A) or
Beta (Panel B) and the amenity values of the MSAs. These
panels demonstrate that the relations
between housing price volatility and amenity, presented in
Table 4, are reliable across the majority
of the observations in the sample and are not driven by a small
segment of the data or a few outliers.
Generally speaking, Table 4 and Figure 2 provide evidence that
housing price volatility is
higher in more attractive MSAs. These results are consistent
with the hypothesis presented in our
theoretical section. Moreover, our empirical results are in line
with the land leverage hypothesis
presented by Bostic, Longhofer and Redfrean (2007), since
higher amenity values are associated
with higher land share values.
Table 5 reports the results from regression specifications (4.1)
and (4.2), which control for
geographical regions. As in Table 4, columns (1) through (4)
and (5) through (8) use standard
deviation and Beta, respectively, as the measure for housing
price volatility. Columns (1), (2), (5)
and (6) use the U.S. Census definition for the 4 major regions as
region controls and columns (3),
(4), (7) and (8) use the Census definition for the 9 sub regions.
In all the columns reported within
the table, the coefficient of Amenity or Quality and Productivity
is positive and statistically
significant. These results solidify our findings manifested in
Table 4 and suggest that the positive
relation between amenity values and housing price volatility
areas is not due to specific regional
area. With that said, the negative coefficient of the Midwest
variable and the positive coefficient
of the West variable (both statistically significant when
standard deviation is used as a volatility
measure) indicate that overall volatility is lower in the Midwest
and higher in the West even once
amenity values are accounted for.
Panels A through D of Figure 3 illustrate the relation between
Amenity and housing price
volatility in each of the four US Census regions. Each panel
includes a fitted value line for the
region as well as a fitted line for the US as a whole. These
panels show that the positive correlation
between housing price volatility and amenity value exists in
each of the four regions. However, it
appears that the relation between amenity values and volatility
is generally less pronounced in the
Midwest and the West, as it is evident by the steepness of their
fitted values relative to the steepness
of the full sample fitted value line.
While, on average, higher housing price volatility appears to
take place in areas with higher
amenity value and vice versa, it is possible that this positive
relation between volatility and amenity
is driven mostly by periods of particular market price trend.
Given that high volatility during a
general downtrend in housing prices (severe price declines) is
more concerning than high volatility
during a general uptrend trend in housing prices (sharp price
increases) the symmetry in the
relation between volatility and amenity should be explored.
Table 6 show the results from specifications (2.1) and (2.2)
when the dependent variable
captures housing price volatility either during the “up” or
“down” market periods included in our
sample. A glance at the table reveals that the coefficients of the
Quality and Productivity or
Amenity variables are positive and statistically significant in
each of the eight columns included in
the table. Moreover, when the coefficients from the uptrend
periods (columns (1) and (2), for
example) are compared with those from the downtrend periods
(columns (3) and (4), for example)
their magnitude is very similar. These results suggest that
positive relation between price volatility
and amenity values, which was documented in the previous
tables, also exhibits high level of
symmetry.
Performance and Amenities
In traditional financial markets, assets that are paired with
higher rate of return expectations
are often accompanied by higher levels of risk. Recall from our
Theory and Hypothesis
Development section that we consider a case where amenity
contribution increases as permanent
incomes increase with economic growth. Under this likely case
home price appreciation over time
will be higher in areas with greater levels of amenities. On the
other hand, we receive ambiguous
results when we theoretically examine the relation between
amenities and risk-adjusted price
appreciation.
Table 7 displays the results from our price performance
analysis. Columns (1) and (2)
report the results from specifications (5.1) and (5.2), which
examine the relation between housing
amenities and raw rates of real housing price appreciation. In
these columns the coefficients of the
Quality and Productivity or Amenity variables are all positive
and statistically significant. These
results are consistent with our theoretical prediction and imply
that, when risk is not considered,
housing price appreciation is higher in areas with higher
amenity value and vice versa. Columns
(3) though (6) report the relation between amenities and risk-
adjusted price appreciation measured
with Alpha (columns (3) and (4)) or with Sharpe ratio (columns
(5) and (6)) as per equations (6)
and (7), respectively. As with our theoretical prediction, these
empirical results are also
ambiguous. When Alpha is employed as the measure of risk-
adjusted price appreciation, the
observed relation is marginally negative with some statistical
significance. However, when risk-
adjusted return is measured with the Sharpe ratio the observed
relation is positive and statistically
significant.
Figure 4 provides a graphical illustration of the relation
between amenity levels and
housing real returns on a raw and risk-adjusted basis. Consistent
with the results reported in Table
7, the panels of Figure 4 show positive relation between real
returns and amenities, negative
relation between Alpha and amenities and positive relation
between Sharpe ratio and amenities.
The panels included in Figure 4 also provide evidence that these
relations are relatively consistent
throughout the sample and not driven by a handful of extreme
observations.
Quintile Analysis
As an additional robustness test we examine the relation
between local amenities and risk,
returns and risk-adjusted return within subsamples of our
dataset. Specifically, we segment the
MSAs included in our dataset into quintiles based on their total
amenity values. We then measure
the average risk and return values within each quintile over the
full time period as well as during
our previously defined up and down markets. This type of
analysis allows us to better determine
whether monotonous trends in the relation between amenities
and price performance can be
observed.
Table 8 reports the results of our quintile analysis. Consistent
with the results we previously
present in this paper, housing price appreciation in real terms
(real returns), housing price volatility
(measured by Beta or Standard Deviation) and the Sharpe ratio
of housing are increasing with the
level of local amenities. Also consistent with our previous
results, the Alpha of housing is
decreasing with the level of housing amenities. For each of
these five measures the increase or
decrease from the low (quintile 1) to the high quintile (quintile
5) of amenities is mostly
monotonous. Moreover, the difference between our housing
performance measures and amenities
is statistically significant at the 1% level. Additionally, the
differences between the levels of these
measures when comparing quintile 1 to quintile 5 all (with the
exception of Alpha during up
markets) carry their expected sign and are keep their statistical
significance.
The monotonous change in the average values of our risk, return
and risk adjusted return
measures across quintiles provides evidence that the general
relation we observe between
amenities and housing price changes holds for subsets of the
data regardless of the direction of the
overall market. Overall, Table 8 strengthens the validity of the
general results presented in this
paper and showcases their robustness.
Conclusion
This paper utilizes previously estimated values for local
amenities in order to determine
the relation between the level of amenities observed in different
location and housing price
volatility and rate of appreciation in these locations. We
document that amenity levels are
positively related to housing price volatility as well as to raw
rates of price appreciation. When
risk is considered, however, amenities are positively related to
risk-adjusted rate of appreciation
when measured in absolute terms (Sharpe ratio), but negatively
related to risk-adjusted price
appreciation when measured in relative terms (Alpha). Overall,
our empirical results are consistent
with our theoretical model that predicts higher volatility and
price appreciation in areas associated
with more amenities and ambiguity with respect the risk
adjusted returns.
Previous research provide evidence for higher housing price
volatility in selected large
cities due to a land leverage effect (Nichols, Oliner and Mulhall
(2013)). Our research makes an
important contribution to the existing literature by applying
land value proxies in order to provide
a much broader empirical evidence to the elevated housing price
volatility in more attractive
locations. Moreover, by using a broader set of locations, we are
also able to examine the extent to
which housing price appreciation is related to locations’
amenity values, which to our knowledge,
was never examined in much detail previously.
References
Albouy, D., 2009. What Are Cities worth? Land Rents, Local
Productivity, and the Capitalization
of Amenity Values, National Bureau Economic Research
Working Paper No. 14981.
Albouy, D., Ehrlich. G., 2012. Metropolitan Land Values and
Housing Productivity. National
Bureau Economic Research Working Paper No. 18110.
Albouy, D., Ehrlich. G., 2013. The Distribution of Urban Land
Values: Evidence from Market
Transactions. Working paper.
Black, S., 1999. Do Better Schools Matter? Parental Valuation
of Elementary Education. Quarterly
Journal of Economics 114, 577-600.
Bogart, W.T., Cromwell, B.A., 2000. How Much Is a
Neighborhood School Worth? Journal of
Urban Economics 47, 280-305.
Bostic, R.W., Longhofer, S.D., Redfearn, C.L., 2006. Assessing
Land Taxation Regimes: Revenue
Volatility and Land Leverage. Working paper.
Bostic, R.W., Longhofer, S.D., Redfrean, C.L., 2007. Land
Leverage: Decomposing Home Price
Dynamics. Real Estate Economics 35, 183-208.
Davis, M.A., Palumbo, M.G., 2007. The Price of Residential
Land in Large US Cities. Journal of
Urban Economics 63, 352-384.
Dolde, W., Tirtiroglu D., 2002. Housing Price Volatility
Changes and Their Effects. Real Estate
Economics 30, 41-66.
Glaeser, E.L., Gyourko, J., 2003. The Impact of Building
Restrictions on Housing Affordability.
FRB New York - Economic Policy Review 9, 21-39.
Glaeser, E.L., Gyourko, J., Saiz A., 2008. Housing Supply and
Housing Bubbles. Journal of Urban
Economics 64, 198-217.
Glaeser, E.L., Gyourko, J., Saks, R.E., 2005. Why Have
Housing Prices Gone Up? The American
Economic Review 95(5), 329-333.
Grimes, A., Aitken, A., 2010. Housing Supply, Land Costs, and
Price Adjustment. Real Estate
Economics 38, 325-353.
Gyourko, J., Saiz, A., Summers, A., 2008. A New Measure of
The Local Regulatory Environment
for Housing Markets: The Wharton residential land use
regulatory index. Urban Studies
45, 693-729.
Kok, N., Monkkonen, P., Quigley, J.M., 2014. Land Use
Regulations and the Value of Land and
Housing: An Intra-Metropolitan Analysis. Journal of Urban
Economics, Forthcoming.
Landry, C.E., Hindsley, P., 2011. Valuing Beach Quality with
Hedonic Property Models, Land
Economics 87, 92-108.
Miao, H., Ramchander, S., Simpson, M.W., 2011. Return and
Volatility Transmission in U.S.
Housing Markets. Real Estate Economics 39, 701-741.
Moretti, E., 2004. Estimating the Social Return to Higher
Education: Evidence from Longitudinal
and Repeated Cross-Sectional Data. Journal of
Econometrics121, 175-212.
Nichols, J.B., Oliner, S.D., Mulhall, M.R., 2013. Swings in
Commercial and Residential Land
Prices in the United States. Journal of Urban Economics 73, 57-
76.
Paciorek, A., 2013. Supply Constraints and Housing Market
Dynamics. Journal of Urban
Economics 77, 11-26
Rosen, S., 1974. Hedonic Prices and Implicit Markets: Product
Differentiation in Pure
Competition. Journal of Political Economy 82, 34-55.
Rosenthal, S.S., Strange, W.C., 2008. The Attenuation of
Human Capital Spillovers, Journal of
Urban Economics 64, 373-389.
Saiz, A., 2010. The Geographic Determinants of Housing
Supply. The Quarterly Journal of
Economics 125, 1253-1296.
Turnbull, G. K., Zahirovic-Herbert V., Mothorpe, C., 2013.
Flooding and Liquidity on the Bayou:
The Capitalization of Flood Risk into House Value and Ease-of-
Sale, Real Estate
Economics 41, 103-129.
Sirmans, C.F., Slade, B.A., 2012. National Transaction-Based
Land Price Indices. The Journal of
Real Estate Finance and Economics 45, 829-845.
Wyman, D., Hutchinson N., Tiwari, P., 2014. Testing the
Waters: A Spatial Econometric Pricing
Model of Different Waterfront Views, Journal of Real Estate
Research 36, 363-382.
Zhou, Y., Haurin, D.R., 2010. On the Determinants of House
Volatility. Journal of Real Estate
Research 32, 377-395.
Figure 1. House Prices and Volatility
Panel A: US Inflation-Adjusted Housing Price Index Q1 1975 –
Q3 2013
Note: dotted lines indicate divisions between the up and down
markets in this study
Panel B: Inflation-Adjusted Housing Price Index in Selected
MSAs
90
115
140
165
1
9
7
5
1
9
7
7
1
9
7
9
1
9
8
1
1
9
8
3
1
9
8
5
1
9
8
7
1
9
8
9
1
9
9
1
1
9
9
3
1
9
9
5
1
9
9
7
1
9
9
9
2
0
0
1
2
0
0
3
2
0
0
5
2
0
0
7
2
0
0
9
2
0
1
1
2
0
1
3
In
fl
a
ti
o
n
a
d
ju
st
e
d
i
n
d
e
x
Q
1
1
9
7
5
=
1
0
0
50
75
100
125
150
175
1
9
7
5
1
9
7
7
1
9
7
9
1
9
8
1
1
9
8
3
1
9
8
5
1
9
8
7
1
9
8
9
1
9
9
1
1
9
9
3
1
9
9
5
1
9
9
7
1
9
9
9
2
0
0
1
2
0
0
3
2
0
0
5
2
0
0
7
2
0
0
9
2
0
1
1
In
fl
a
ti
o
n
A
d
ju
st
e
d
H
P
I
Q
1
2
0
0
2
=
1
0
0
Louisville, KY Stockton, CA
Figure 2. Volatility and amenity values
Figure 3: Housing volatilities vs. amenities (by region)
0
.0
5
.1
.1
5
-.2 -.1 0 .1 .2 .3
US East
East Region
0
.0
5
.1
.1
5
-.2 -.1 0 .1 .2 .3
US Midwest
Midwest Region
0
.0
5
.1
.1
5
-.2 -.1 0 .1 .2 .3
US South
South Region
0
.0
5
.1
.1
5
-.2 -.1 0 .1 .2 .3
US West
West Region
S
ta
n
d
a
rd
D
e
v
ia
ti
o
n
Amenity
Figure 4. Housing returns vs. amenities
-.
0
5
0
.0
5
-.2 -.1 0 .1 .2 .3
Amenity
Panel A. Real Returns
-.
0
2
0
.0
2
-.2 -.1 0 .1 .2 .3
Amenity
Panel B. Alpha (systematic risk adjusted returns)
-.
5
0
.5
-.2 -.1 0 .1 .2 .3
Amenity
Panel C. Sharpe Ratio (total risk adjusted returns)
Table 1. Quality of life, trade-productivity and amenity values
for selected MSAs
Total
Amenities
Quality of Life
Trade
Productivity
Metropolitan area Value Rank Value Rank Value Rank
Total Amenities: Top 5 metro areas
San Francisco-Oakland-San Jose, CA 0.323 1 0.138 3 0.289 1
Santa Barbara-Santa Maria-Lompoc, CA 0.255 2 0.176 2 0.125
7
Honolulu, HI 0.24 3 0.204 1 0.057 22
Salinas (Monterey-Carmel), CA 0.229 4 0.137 4 0.144 4
San Diego, CA 0.185 5 0.123 7 0.098 11
Total Amenities : Bottom 5 metro areas
Joplin, MO -0.168 261 -0.011 118 -0.246 272
Fort Smith, AR-OK -0.169 262 -0.045 206 -0.194 255
Johnstown, PA -0.191 272 -0.062 250 -0.201 258
Brownsville-Harlingen-San Benito, TX -0.198 274 -0.057 238
-0.221 267
McAllen-Edinburg-Mission, TX -0.225 276 -0.079 272 -0.228
270
Quality of Life: Top 5 metro areas
Honolulu, HI 0.24 3 0.204 1 0.057 22
Santa Barbara-Santa Maria-Lompoc, CA 0.255 2 0.176 2 0.125
7
San Francisco-Oakland-San Jose, CA 0.323 1 0.138 3 0.289 1
Salinas (Monterey-Carmel), CA 0.229 4 0.137 4 0.144 4
Santa Fe, NM 0.116 12 0.127 5 -0.017 60
Quality of Life: Bottom 5 metro areas
Saginaw-Bay City-Midland, MI -0.096 168 -0.074 270 -0.035
75
McAllen-Edinburg-Mission, TX -0.225 276 -0.079 272 -0.228
270
Decatur, IL -0.14 232 -0.089 274 -0.08 118
Beaumont-Port Arthur, TX -0.153 253 -0.108 275 -0.07 107
Kokomo, IN -0.091 158 -0.11 276 0.029 33
Trade Productivity: Top 5 metro areas
San Francisco-Oakland-San Jose, CA 0.323 1 0.138 3 0.289 1
New York, N.New Jersey, Long Island 0.163 8 0.029 51 0.209
2
Los Angeles-Riverside-Orange Co., CA 0.177 6 0.081 14 0.15
3
Salinas (Monterey-Carmel), CA 0.229 4 0.137 4 0.144 4
Chicago-Gary-Kenosha, IL-IN-WI 0.089 15 0.005 80 0.131 5
Trade Productivity: Bottom 5 metro areas
Brownsville-Harlingen-San Benito, TX -0.198 274 -0.057 238
-0.221 267
Abilene, TX -0.139 231 0.004 83 -0.223 268
Wichita Falls, TX -0.152 251 -0.008 102 -0.226 269
McAllen-Edinburg-Mission, TX -0.225 276 -0.079 272 -0.228
270
Joplin, MO -0.168 261 -0.011 118 -0.246 272
Note: This table illustrates the variation in amenity values
across MSAs, and is a sub-set of the data from
Table A1 of Albouy (2009).
Table 2. Summary statistics
Variables Mean STD Min Max Obs.
House price returns
Total return: over sample period1 1.11 .365 .628 3.72 238
Total return: annual average .024 .006 .014 .042 238
Real return: annual average .003 .008 -.013 .036 238
House price volatility
Standard deviation (annual) .052 .025 .016 .131 238
Beta (quarter) .846 .525 .099 2.71 238
Albouy measures
Quality (quality of life) -.007 .049 -.117 .178 238
Productivity (trade productivity) -.064 .084 -.246 .285 238
Amenity (total amenities) -.048 .082 -.229 .315 238
Heating Days (heating degree days) 3,160 1,727 0 8,194 237
Cooling Days (cooling degree days) 2,690 1,341 10 6,487 237
Precipitation (annual rainfall, inches) 37 14 3 66 238
Coast (coastal/great lakes, 1/0) .328 .471 0 1 238
Census measures (year 2000)
Population 928,577 2,080,520 101,541 21,000,000 238
Education (% bachelor degree 25+) .279 .098 .053 .642 238
Income (median household income) 48,736 7,657 31,264 85,660
238
Saiz (2010) measure
Elasticity (land supply elasticity) 2 2.57 1.36 .62 7.94 208
Davis and Palumbo (2007) measure
Land Share (%, land value/total value) .358 .180 .093 .821 40
Note: 1) The sample is an unbalanced panel dataset. Sample
time frame has an average of 125 quarters (72
min, 153 max) per MSA from 1975 to 2013. 2) Although Saiz
(2010) covers 95 MSAs/NECMAs, we infer
elasticities for smaller geographic areas in our sample that
comprise those metropolitan areas based on a
weighted average of population.
Table 3. Correlation matrix
Land Share Amenities Quality Productivity Elasticity
Land Share 1 .800*** .764*** .567*** -.598***
Amenities .837*** 1 .692*** .856*** -.619***
Quality .815*** .771*** 1 .288* -.699***
Productivity .635*** .815*** .261*** 1 -.302**
Elasticity -.566*** -.561*** -.414*** -.482*** 1
Notes: The upper diagonal reports Spearman correlation
coefficients. The bottom diagonal reports Pearson
correlation coefficients. The symbols ***,**,* indicate
statistical significance at the 1%, 5%, and 10%
level, respectively.
Table 4. Regression analysis: volatility, amenities and area
characteristics
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8)
Variables Standard Deviation (total volatility) Beta
(systematic volatility)
Quality 0.226*** 0.101*** 4.131*** 2.073***
[8.34] [2.89] [6.82] [2.43]
Productivity 0.094*** 0.042 1.966*** 1.692***
[5.97] [1.57] [5.59] [2.63]
Amenity 0.183*** 0.088*** 3.564*** 2.307***
[11.67] [2.93] [10.18] [3.16]
Population -0.004** -0.005** -0.097*** -0.088***
[-2.83] [-3.76] [-2.65] [-2.79]
Education -0.054*** -0.051*** -1.019*** -1.076***
[-4.10] [-4.08] [-3.15] [-3.54]
Heating Days -0.000*** -0.000*** -0.000*** -0.000***
[-4.73] [-4.74] [-2.98] [-2.96]
Cooling Days -0.000 -0.000 0.000 0.000
[0.21] [-0.12] [0.45] [0.42]
Precipitation -0.000*** -0.000*** -0.007*** -0.007***
[-4.61] [-4.66] [-3.18] [-3.16]
Coastal/Lakes 0.005* 0.005* .083 0.082
[1.85] [1.84] [1.22] [1.21]
ln(Income) .044*** 0.041*** 0.463 0.506
[3.19] [3.09] [1.37] [1.56]
Elasticity -0.004*** -0.004*** -.103*** -0.101***
[-3.87] [-4.02] [-3.98] [-3.95]
Constant 0.059*** 0.060*** -0.304** 0.263* 1.002***
1.018*** -1.690*** -2.281***
[36.92] [40.61] [2.07] [-1.91] [27.95] [30.76] [-0.47] [-0.68]
Obs. 238 238 207 207 238 238 207 207
Adj. R^2 0.3699 0.3634 0.632 0.633 0.303 0.302 0.526 0.529
Notes: The symbols ***,**,* indicate statistical significance at
the 1%, 5%, and 10% level, respectively. The observations
decrease in
Models (3, 4, 7 and 8) due to missing data for some of the
independent variables.
Table 5. Regression analysis: volatility and amenities (with
regional controls)
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8)
Variables Standard Deviation (total volatility) Beta
(systematic volatility)
Quality 0.126*** 0.0836*** 2.451*** 1.338**
[4.52] [2.98] [3.72] [2.05]
Productivity 0.085*** 0.0697*** 1.836*** 1.505***
[5.55] [4.50] [5.05] [4.18]
Amenity 0.130*** 0.098*** 2.689*** 1.913***
[7.98] [5.86] [6.95] [4.91]
Midwest -0.013*** -0.014*** -0.119 -0.119
[-3.40] [-3.41] [-1.23] [-1.24]
South 0.000 0.000 0.080 0.070
[0.06] [0.02] [0.85] [0.77]
West 0.018*** 0.017*** 0.378*** 0.366***
[3.79] [3.86] [3.44] [3.44]
MA -0.024*** -0.024*** -0.341* -0.332*
[-2.96] [-2.94] [-1.83] [-1.78]
ENC -0.033*** -0.033*** -0.396** -0.381**
[-4.38] [-4.34] [-2.24] [-2.16]
WNC -0.032*** -0.034*** -0.425 -0.437
[-4.14] [-4.19] [-2.28] [-2.35]
SA -0.013* -0.013* 0.042 0.016
[-1.67] [-1.78] [0.24] [0.09]
ESC -0.031*** -0.032*** -0.366* -0.371*
[-3.71] [-3.73] [-1.92] [-1.94]
WSC -0.022*** -0.023*** -0.474** -0.490***
[-2.83] [-2.89] [-2.59] [-2.69]
MTN -0.007 -0.007 0.073 0.040
[-0.80] [-0.91] [0.39] [0.22]
P 0.084 0.0076 0.4252 0.4203
[1.05] [1.01] [1.55] [1.47]
Constant 0.0584*** 0.0585*** 0.0758*** 0.0757*** 0.8830***
0.8819*** 1.0596*** 1.0580***
[16.64] [16.72] [11.2289] [11.2300] [9.8210] [9.8379]
[6.0716] [6.0759]
Obs. 238 238 238 238 238 238 238 238
Adj R^2 0.497 0.499 0.547 0.548 0.369 0.372 0.456 0.455
Note: The symbols ***,**,* indicate statistical significance at
the 1%, 5%, and 10% level, respectively
Table 6. Regression analysis: volatility (by up and down market
segmentation)
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8)
Up Markets Down Markets Up Markets Down Markets
Variables Volatility (Standard Deviation) Volatility (Beta)
Quality 0.186*** 0.187*** 4.980 *** 3.731***
[7.56] [7.12] [5.88] [5.75]
Productivity 0.057*** 0.057*** 0.882* 1.234***
[3.96] [3.76] [1.79] [3.27]
Amenity 0.134*** 0.134*** 3.050*** 2.764***
[9.30] [8.79] [6.15] [7.32]
Constant 0.049*** 0.051*** 0.051*** 0.053*** 1.031***
1.09*** 1.06*** 1.09***
[33.84] [37.33] [33.39] [36.83] [20.68] [23.26] [27.53] [30.44]
Obs. 238 238 238 238 238 238 238 238
Adj. R^2 0.282 0.265 0.259 0.243 0.158 0.134 0.190 0.182
Notes: The symbols ***,**,* indicate statistical significance
at the 1%, 5%, and 10% level, respectively. Models (1, 2, 5,
and 6) utilize observations from “up markets” (appreciating),
while the other models utilize observations from down
markets (depreciating).
Table 7. Regression analysis: returns and risk-adjusted returns
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)
Variables Real Returns (annual) Alpha (quarterly) Sharpe
Ratio (annual)
Quality 0.078*** 0.006 1.191***
[8.14] [0.98] [5.30]
Productivity 0.011*** -0.009** -0.085
[2.16] [-2.43] [-0.69]
Amenity 0.044*** -0.005 0.445***
[7.42] [-1.26] [3.21]
Regional
Fixed Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
Effects
Constant 0.017*** 0.018*** 0.001 0.001 0.219***
0.224***
[7.39] [7.19] [0.71] [0.74] [4.00] [3.94]
Obs. 238 238 238 238 238 238
Adj. R^2 0.521 0.482 0.249 0.237 0.293 0.243
Note: The symbols ***,**,* indicate statistical significance at
the 1%, 5%, and 10% level,
respectively.
Table 8. Quintile analysis: risk, returns, and risk-adjusted
returns
Real returns (annual)
All markets 0.33% *** 0.08% 0.01% -0.01% 0.38% *** 1.24%
*** 1.16% ***
Up markets 2.02% *** 0.91% *** 0.94% *** 1.59% *** 2.50%
*** 4.30% *** 3.39% ***
Down markets -2.21% *** -1.14% *** -1.44% *** -2.33% *** -
2.87% *** -3.36% *** -2.22% ***
Alpha (annualized)
All markets 0.29% ** 1.16% *** 0.82% *** 0.18% -0.18% -
0.59% * -1.75% ***
Up markets -0.67% *** 0.11% 0.02% -1.27% ** -1.53% ** -
0.69% -0.80%
Down markets 0.91% *** 2.03% *** 1.74% *** 0.83% ***
0.39% -0.57% -2.61% ***
Sharpe ratio (real return per unit of standard deviation, annual)
All markets 0.052 *** 0.033 0.002 0.002 0.068 *** 0.162 ***
0.129 ***
Up markets 0.432 *** 0.313 *** 0.274 *** 0.386 *** 0.528 ***
0.672 *** 0.359 ***
Down markets -0.470 *** -0.318 *** -0.379 *** -0.484 *** -
0.606 *** -0.571 *** -0.253 ***
Volatility (standard deviation, annual)
All markets 5.16% *** 3.61% *** 3.97% *** 4.80% *** 5.86%
*** 7.74% *** 4.13% ***
Up markets 4.44% *** 3.31% *** 3.65% *** 4.09% *** 4.89%
*** 6.37% *** 3.05% **
Down markets 4.68% *** 3.48% *** 3.70% *** 4.50% ***
5.14% *** 6.72% *** 3.24% ***
Volatility (Beta, quarterly)
All markets 0.846 *** 0.501 *** 0.606 *** 0.825 *** 1.014 ***
1.317 *** 0.817 ***
Up markets 0.944 *** 0.603 *** 0.647 *** 0.989 *** 1.180 ***
1.333 *** 0.729 ***
Down markets 0.953 *** 0.663 *** 0.820 *** 0.903 *** 1.076
*** 1.327 *** 0.664 ***
AmenityAmenity Amenity Amenity Amenity Amenity
Quintiles
Sample (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (5-1)
Full Quintile Quintile Quintile Quintile Quintile
Notes: Quintiles based on Amenity (1 = low amenities, 5 = high
amenities). The symbols ***,**,* indicate statistical
significance at the 1%,
5%, and 10% level, respectively.
Problem 1YearQQuartely return - CRE_Atlanta_GAQuarterly
return - CRE_Denver_COQuarterly return - CRE_USAInflation
index19774100.00197813.24%2.58%2.90%102.09a. Correlation
between Altalnta and Denver for the 1990:1-2014:2 time
period21.76%2.25%3.07%104.9931.54%8.50%3.39%107.0943.9
8%9.50%5.89%109.02b. Correlation between Denver and the
USA for the 1978:1- 2014:2 time
period197912.75%4.09%3.81%112.4023.33%1.82%4.32%116.4
332.76%2.23%4.75%120.13c. Correlation between USA and
inflation rate for the 1995:1 - 2014:2 time
period48.68%6.97%6.19%123.51198012.15%5.00%5.54%128.9
923.27%2.77%2.36%133.17d. The annual standard deviation of
returns for the USA for the 1990:1-2014:2 time
period32.17%2.21%3.79%135.2746.82%9.43%5.32%138.97198
112.21%6.71%2.96%142.51e. The 3-year standard deviation of
returns for the USA for the 1990:1-2014:2 time
period23.13%2.63%4.23%145.8930.63%0.59%3.21%150.0845.6
1%27.87%5.29%151.37f. The geometric average USA annual
returns for the 1990:1-2014:2 time
period198212.43%1.73%2.49%152.1723.30%0.40%2.07%156.2
032.48%2.69%1.52%157.6542.97%0.91%3.04%157.17198311.7
4%1.89%1.75%157.6523.25%1.47%2.54%160.2334.52%2.06%2
.96%162.1644.30%4.10%5.31%163.12198412.99%2.24%3.35%
165.2224.14%3.78%3.16%166.9932.56%0.45%2.46%169.0843.
48%0.99%4.21%169.57198514.30%-
0.95%2.08%171.3423.53%1.89%2.60%173.2731.58%1.31%2.39
%174.4044.11%4.31%3.73%176.01198612.90%0.46%2.03%175
.2022.49%1.49%1.96%176.3332.82%-
1.50%1.50%177.4640.97%-
1.94%2.57%177.94198711.35%1.28%1.83%180.5220.71%-
1.81%1.19%182.7730.27%0.24%2.09%185.1940.74%-
1.11%2.67%185.83198811.22%0.63%1.84%187.6021.39%-
0.43%2.00%190.0230.30%0.68%2.39%192.9141.39%2.11%3.07
%194.04198912.29%0.56%1.75%196.942-
0.24%0.78%2.00%199.8430.55%1.68%2.05%201.2940.76%-
3.46%1.75%203.06199011.90%0.34%1.38%207.2520.25%1.28
%1.52%209.183-2.18%-0.10%0.84%213.694-1.87%-3.34%-
1.43%215.4619911-2.23%-2.10%0.05%217.3920.70%-
0.51%0.01%219.003-1.05%-0.31%-0.33%220.934-6.05%-
4.34%-5.33%222.06199210.41%-0.83%-0.03%224.322-
0.79%0.34%-1.03%225.7630.20%-1.24%-0.44%227.5440.13%-
1.65%-2.81%228.50199311.84%1.79%0.77%231.2422.34%-
8.31%-0.24%232.5332.06%1.84%1.10%233.6642.84%1.66%-
0.25%234.78199411.98%1.98%1.31%237.0423.74%3.35%1.54
%238.3333.69%2.77%1.51%240.5844.15%4.96%1.88%241.061
99513.39%2.43%2.11%243.8023.31%2.06%2.08%245.5732.85
%2.53%2.06%246.7043.09%-
1.15%1.09%247.18199612.57%2.33%2.40%250.7223.04%3.06
%2.29%252.3332.39%2.48%2.63%254.1144.58%2.74%2.61%25
5.39199712.46%2.80%2.34%257.6522.72%2.68%2.82%258.133
3.65%2.75%3.38%259.5845.35%3.63%4.71%259.74199812.36
%5.43%4.14%261.1923.73%6.67%4.19%262.4833.06%3.30%3.
46%263.4542.55%3.15%3.55%263.93199912.58%3.03%2.59%2
65.7022.05%3.12%2.62%267.6332.64%3.71%2.81%270.3742.3
7%2.55%2.89%271.01200012.12%4.09%2.40%275.6822.39%3.
78%3.05%277.6231.99%1.84%2.94%279.7142.35%2.72%3.33%
280.19200112.24%2.05%2.36%283.7422.00%1.84%2.47%286.6
331.53%0.75%1.60%287.1240.02%0.32%0.67%284.54200211.3
6%2.34%1.51%287.9221.18%1.10%1.61%289.6931.02%-
0.07%1.79%291.4740.30%0.35%1.67%291.30200310.81%1.12
%1.88%296.6221.39%0.93%2.09%295.8130.87%2.64%1.97%29
8.2341.61%1.16%2.76%296.78200412.27%1.13%2.56%301.772
2.00%1.39%3.13%305.4832.73%3.61%3.42%305.8043.78%2.07
%4.66%306.44200512.47%4.47%3.51%311.2724.05%4.24%5.3
4%313.2034.10%4.78%4.44%320.1344.76%3.85%5.43%316.91
200613.07%3.00%3.62%321.7424.06%4.06%4.01%326.7333.54
%3.10%3.51%326.7343.10%3.85%4.51%324.96200712.59%3.3
3%3.62%330.6823.18%5.01%4.59%335.5131.95%2.63%3.56%3
35.7341.82%3.47%3.21%338.22200811.63%1.20%1.60%343.85
20.36%1.80%0.56%352.363-0.37%0.22%-0.17%352.314-7.03%-
6.04%-8.29%338.5320091-7.43%-7.60%-7.33%342.532-5.30%-
4.56%-5.20%347.333-3.05%-2.75%-3.32%347.784-2.81%-
1.68%-
2.11%347.74201010.95%1.04%0.76%350.4522.29%3.69%3.31
%350.9933.24%4.18%3.86%351.7542.76%6.35%4.62%352.952
01112.79%3.59%3.36%359.8523.20%3.67%3.94%363.4832.80
%3.48%3.30%365.3643.01%3.85%2.96%363.40201212.26%2.8
7%2.59%369.3923.25%3.68%2.68%369.5332.14%2.88%2.34%3
72.6441.97%3.49%2.54%369.73201312.28%2.76%2.57%374.84
22.40%3.85%2.87%376.0132.68%3.35%2.59%377.0543.22%4.2
2%2.53%375.28201412.47%2.97%2.74%380.5023.57%3.44%2.
91%383.81
Problem 2DateKBH priceHME priceSPY
price4/1/1515.4468.48210.63Beta
KBH:3/2/1515.6269.29206.42999Beta
HME:2/2/1513.9566.77209.72385Which company has a higher
Beta?1/2/1512.4348469.71426198.56366In one to two sentences
explain why you did or didn’t expect that company to be
associated with a higher
Beta.12/1/1416.5165864.86887204.6265911/3/1417.5345264.46
344205.1469710/1/1415.6836562.8725199.661879/2/1414.8865
256.93818195.067848/1/1417.6864662.78452197.796717/1/141
6.2169263.58646190.287296/2/1418.5847961.81775192.879145
/1/1416.39660.09737188.977714/1/1416.4258558.84649184.691
683/3/1416.8774357.43264183.416662/3/1420.2648456.305391
81.907641/2/1419.1863252.60588173.9884212/2/1318.1347450.
59601180.3452811/1/1317.390749.61466175.7877210/1/1316.8
102156.2014170.727749/3/1317.8503353.8158163.171788/1/13
15.8790753.7692158.16647/1/1317.5828758.78954163.056856/
3/1319.4163960.22681155.044635/1/1321.9188555.98872157.1
4164/1/1322.2947258.75099153.517113/1/1321.5095157.80311
50.623282/1/1318.4663656.89166145.113161/2/1318.8164555.3
8373143.28512/3/1215.5899355.23957136.307411/1/1214.1690
753.05918135.1003410/1/1215.7675354.16706134.340039/4/12
14.1372754.59477136.830098/1/1210.8763456.89368133.44717
/2/129.1030357.85545130.185616/1/129.6293254.10776128.663
575/1/127.1237352.85559123.645884/2/128.5042653.27468131.
545973/1/128.719853.23978132.430042/1/1211.1887850.29026
128.303311/3/128.7796851.42603122.9659312/1/116.5409649.6
9111117.5161711/1/117.1541747.44695116.3010210/3/116.722
9850.29536116.775579/1/115.6523248.46799105.284118/1/116.
3564457.10103113.138247/1/118.128255.39695119.719926/1/1
19.3632251.47384122.163765/2/1111.7566852.33625124.25999
4/1/1111.2454153.05796125.669323/1/1111.8452949.33386122.
132192/1/1112.6165749.30875122.117521/3/1114.0705746.084
4118.0178912/1/1012.7905745.92714115.3306711/1/1010.7141
144.35458108.1036910/1/109.9048844.60028108.103699/1/101
0.6776743.33066104.125878/2/109.716441.3648195.567367/1/1
010.6678740.20872100.06856/1/1010.3116536.4849493.670725
/3/1013.5738839.3668398.781794/1/1017.3130939.76447107.30
7893/1/1015.6499837.45175105.673122/1/1015.2108536.65159
9.608961/4/1014.217735.0283296.5956912/1/0912.7289437.699
1100.238611/2/0912.6079735.5024298.3598410/1/0913.136013
0.4530292.651859/1/0915.387133.492194.468038/3/0916.86932
9.5125491.233167/1/0915.4046827.2841987.98316/1/0912.6264
826.0613781.874775/1/0913.8448225.4499681.928434/1/0916.6
245127.3107777.40393/2/0912.1256822.9713270.409032/2/098.
1880619.8909964.994311/2/099.761126.2200272.818612/1/081
2.4598129.6609879.3329711/3/0810.6393328.4920878.5633410
/1/0815.1980929.0368984.440999/2/0817.9208241.55811101.14
9548/1/0818.940737.82899111.665477/1/0816.0176438.994671
09.966096/2/0815.1709934.06187110.963195/1/0818.3790336.2
873121.082784/1/0819.9612236.76734119.279683/3/0821.9395
933.5641113.853182/1/0821.2298632.18629114.880471/2/0824.
166132.93156117.9280312/3/0718.9813730.92505125.5169111/
1/0718.3574431.15949126.9464310/1/0724.0472934.94926132.
061519/4/0721.8026535.46582130.293858/1/0726.3963534.541
45125.437647/2/0727.4588531.08261123.848316/1/0733.98476
34.8622127.851365/1/0739.6129238.66865129.748384/2/0737.8
615236.95248125.49173/1/0736.625535.0352120.168732/1/074
2.5137438.81669118.792061/3/0746.3282942.21426121.169091
2/1/0643.816238.91801119.3736811/1/0644.1665240.58583117.
7985710/2/0638.178541.03386115.501779/1/0637.2100337.129
9111.972768/1/0636.326536.94802109.028827/3/0635.9295735.
82217106.700356/1/0638.7434335.64878106.224655/1/0643.26
4231.94326105.94834/3/0651.8118731.71124109.238683/1/065
4.6814232.39593107.8762/1/0656.4065231.29282106.124531/3/
0663.8954428.69802105.5203812/1/0560.9270725.52603103.04
58211/1/0558.5037326.04531103.2433710/3/0554.6423123.919
9498.896639/1/0561.2060824.16622101.292278/1/0562.042232
5.24985100.485847/1/0568.3112227.75781101.436766/1/0563.5
742226.0843497.698675/2/0556.3269424.9808297.550884/25/0
547.3860924.9976394.50548

More Related Content

Similar to nR E E 693 5T o c o m p l e t e th i s e x a m y o u n.docx

Week 4 Assignment 2Self-assessment of Communication Skills.docx
Week 4 Assignment 2Self-assessment of Communication Skills.docxWeek 4 Assignment 2Self-assessment of Communication Skills.docx
Week 4 Assignment 2Self-assessment of Communication Skills.docx
melbruce90096
 
Learning pitch deck week 3
Learning pitch deck week 3Learning pitch deck week 3
Learning pitch deck week 3
Paul Hayes
 
5 1 6 T o w a r d A l t e r n a t i v e s i n H e a l t h .docx
5 1 6  T o w a r d  A l t e r n a t i v e s  i n  H e a l t h .docx5 1 6  T o w a r d  A l t e r n a t i v e s  i n  H e a l t h .docx
5 1 6 T o w a r d A l t e r n a t i v e s i n H e a l t h .docx
alinainglis
 
Startup Weekend Education Delhi April 2012 Facilitator's Deck
Startup Weekend Education Delhi April 2012 Facilitator's DeckStartup Weekend Education Delhi April 2012 Facilitator's Deck
Startup Weekend Education Delhi April 2012 Facilitator's Deck
Nikhil Wason
 

Similar to nR E E 693 5T o c o m p l e t e th i s e x a m y o u n.docx (20)

Financial systems and banking crises, an assessment
Financial systems and banking crises, an assessmentFinancial systems and banking crises, an assessment
Financial systems and banking crises, an assessment
 
Beige Brown Minimal Organic Creative Project Presentation 2.pdf
Beige Brown Minimal Organic Creative Project Presentation 2.pdfBeige Brown Minimal Organic Creative Project Presentation 2.pdf
Beige Brown Minimal Organic Creative Project Presentation 2.pdf
 
Beige Brown Minimal Organic Creative Project Presentation 2.pdf
Beige Brown Minimal Organic Creative Project Presentation 2.pdfBeige Brown Minimal Organic Creative Project Presentation 2.pdf
Beige Brown Minimal Organic Creative Project Presentation 2.pdf
 
From Phonology to Syntax: Unsupervised Linguistic Typology at Different Level...
From Phonology to Syntax: Unsupervised Linguistic Typology at Different Level...From Phonology to Syntax: Unsupervised Linguistic Typology at Different Level...
From Phonology to Syntax: Unsupervised Linguistic Typology at Different Level...
 
Energy Reconsidered
Energy ReconsideredEnergy Reconsidered
Energy Reconsidered
 
Week 4 Assignment 2Self-assessment of Communication Skills.docx
Week 4 Assignment 2Self-assessment of Communication Skills.docxWeek 4 Assignment 2Self-assessment of Communication Skills.docx
Week 4 Assignment 2Self-assessment of Communication Skills.docx
 
Le magazine Paranoia, Automne 2003. Vol 10, No 2, Issue 33
Le magazine Paranoia, Automne 2003. Vol 10, No 2, Issue 33Le magazine Paranoia, Automne 2003. Vol 10, No 2, Issue 33
Le magazine Paranoia, Automne 2003. Vol 10, No 2, Issue 33
 
PARASITIC COMPUTING: PROBLEMS AND ETHICAL CONSIDERATION
PARASITIC COMPUTING: PROBLEMS AND ETHICAL CONSIDERATIONPARASITIC COMPUTING: PROBLEMS AND ETHICAL CONSIDERATION
PARASITIC COMPUTING: PROBLEMS AND ETHICAL CONSIDERATION
 
Metodo de einsten capacidad de transporte
Metodo de einsten   capacidad de transporteMetodo de einsten   capacidad de transporte
Metodo de einsten capacidad de transporte
 
The Library As Indicator Species: Evolution, or Extinction?
The Library As Indicator Species: Evolution, or Extinction?The Library As Indicator Species: Evolution, or Extinction?
The Library As Indicator Species: Evolution, or Extinction?
 
IS Report 3
IS Report 3IS Report 3
IS Report 3
 
Learning pitch deck week 3
Learning pitch deck week 3Learning pitch deck week 3
Learning pitch deck week 3
 
5 1 6 T o w a r d A l t e r n a t i v e s i n H e a l t h .docx
5 1 6  T o w a r d  A l t e r n a t i v e s  i n  H e a l t h .docx5 1 6  T o w a r d  A l t e r n a t i v e s  i n  H e a l t h .docx
5 1 6 T o w a r d A l t e r n a t i v e s i n H e a l t h .docx
 
Econ204 final presentation-Jialin Li-Duke Kunshan University
Econ204 final presentation-Jialin Li-Duke Kunshan University Econ204 final presentation-Jialin Li-Duke Kunshan University
Econ204 final presentation-Jialin Li-Duke Kunshan University
 
Managing a Crisis in the New World of Social Media
Managing a Crisis in the New World of Social MediaManaging a Crisis in the New World of Social Media
Managing a Crisis in the New World of Social Media
 
TMK.edu Traditional Media Buying Presentation: August 2015
TMK.edu Traditional Media Buying Presentation: August 2015TMK.edu Traditional Media Buying Presentation: August 2015
TMK.edu Traditional Media Buying Presentation: August 2015
 
Lesson 5 Conferences with vocabulary and activities.pdf
Lesson 5 Conferences with vocabulary and activities.pdfLesson 5 Conferences with vocabulary and activities.pdf
Lesson 5 Conferences with vocabulary and activities.pdf
 
Startup Weekend Education Delhi April 2012 Facilitator's Deck
Startup Weekend Education Delhi April 2012 Facilitator's DeckStartup Weekend Education Delhi April 2012 Facilitator's Deck
Startup Weekend Education Delhi April 2012 Facilitator's Deck
 
Japan Lease, English
Japan Lease, EnglishJapan Lease, English
Japan Lease, English
 
Underwater Diagnosis
Underwater DiagnosisUnderwater Diagnosis
Underwater Diagnosis
 

More from henrymartin15260

NT2580 Week 1 Understanding IT Infrastructure Security An.docx
NT2580 Week 1 Understanding IT Infrastructure Security An.docxNT2580 Week 1 Understanding IT Infrastructure Security An.docx
NT2580 Week 1 Understanding IT Infrastructure Security An.docx
henrymartin15260
 
NTC362 Week 3OSI Model, Switching Systems, Network Channel Pr.docx
NTC362   Week 3OSI Model, Switching Systems, Network Channel Pr.docxNTC362   Week 3OSI Model, Switching Systems, Network Channel Pr.docx
NTC362 Week 3OSI Model, Switching Systems, Network Channel Pr.docx
henrymartin15260
 
NT2580 Week 4 Hardening a NetworkAnalysis 4.2Availability, In.docx
NT2580 Week 4 Hardening a NetworkAnalysis 4.2Availability, In.docxNT2580 Week 4 Hardening a NetworkAnalysis 4.2Availability, In.docx
NT2580 Week 4 Hardening a NetworkAnalysis 4.2Availability, In.docx
henrymartin15260
 
NTNU, May 2009 ntnu.nocbm 1 LEARNING AND MEMORY .docx
NTNU, May 2009 ntnu.nocbm 1 LEARNING AND MEMORY .docxNTNU, May 2009 ntnu.nocbm 1 LEARNING AND MEMORY .docx
NTNU, May 2009 ntnu.nocbm 1 LEARNING AND MEMORY .docx
henrymartin15260
 
nowHow to be Army StrongI was 18 years old when I saw my fa.docx
nowHow to be Army StrongI was 18 years old when I saw my fa.docxnowHow to be Army StrongI was 18 years old when I saw my fa.docx
nowHow to be Army StrongI was 18 years old when I saw my fa.docx
henrymartin15260
 
NR-351 Transitions in Professional NursingWebsite Evaluation T.docx
NR-351 Transitions in Professional NursingWebsite Evaluation T.docxNR-351 Transitions in Professional NursingWebsite Evaluation T.docx
NR-351 Transitions in Professional NursingWebsite Evaluation T.docx
henrymartin15260
 
Ntc 362 Week 2, Integrative Network Design Project , Part 1By Alucar.docx
Ntc 362 Week 2, Integrative Network Design Project , Part 1By Alucar.docxNtc 362 Week 2, Integrative Network Design Project , Part 1By Alucar.docx
Ntc 362 Week 2, Integrative Network Design Project , Part 1By Alucar.docx
henrymartin15260
 
NTHEMIND OF GREATCOMPANIESBy Scott BlanchardThe.docx
NTHEMIND OF GREATCOMPANIESBy Scott BlanchardThe.docxNTHEMIND OF GREATCOMPANIESBy Scott BlanchardThe.docx
NTHEMIND OF GREATCOMPANIESBy Scott BlanchardThe.docx
henrymartin15260
 
NSG6001 Advanced Practice Nursing I Page 1 of 5 © 2007 S.docx
NSG6001 Advanced Practice Nursing I Page 1 of 5 © 2007 S.docxNSG6001 Advanced Practice Nursing I Page 1 of 5 © 2007 S.docx
NSG6001 Advanced Practice Nursing I Page 1 of 5 © 2007 S.docx
henrymartin15260
 
NR360 We Can But Dare We.docx Revised 5 ‐ 9 .docx
NR360   We   Can   But   Dare   We.docx   Revised   5 ‐ 9 .docxNR360   We   Can   But   Dare   We.docx   Revised   5 ‐ 9 .docx
NR360 We Can But Dare We.docx Revised 5 ‐ 9 .docx
henrymartin15260
 
ns;,eilrlt.lnterviewing is one HR function.docx
ns;,eilrlt.lnterviewing is one HR function.docxns;,eilrlt.lnterviewing is one HR function.docx
ns;,eilrlt.lnterviewing is one HR function.docx
henrymartin15260
 
NR443 Guidelines for Caring for PopulationsMilestone 2 As.docx
NR443 Guidelines for Caring for PopulationsMilestone 2 As.docxNR443 Guidelines for Caring for PopulationsMilestone 2 As.docx
NR443 Guidelines for Caring for PopulationsMilestone 2 As.docx
henrymartin15260
 
NRB Dec’99 1WHITHER THE EMERGENCY MANAGER 1Neil R Bri.docx
NRB Dec’99 1WHITHER THE EMERGENCY MANAGER 1Neil R Bri.docxNRB Dec’99 1WHITHER THE EMERGENCY MANAGER 1Neil R Bri.docx
NRB Dec’99 1WHITHER THE EMERGENCY MANAGER 1Neil R Bri.docx
henrymartin15260
 
Now, its time to create that treasure map to hide the treasur.docx
Now, its time to create that treasure map to hide the treasur.docxNow, its time to create that treasure map to hide the treasur.docx
Now, its time to create that treasure map to hide the treasur.docx
henrymartin15260
 
NR361 Information Systems in HealthcareInterview with a Nursing.docx
NR361 Information Systems in HealthcareInterview with a Nursing.docxNR361 Information Systems in HealthcareInterview with a Nursing.docx
NR361 Information Systems in HealthcareInterview with a Nursing.docx
henrymartin15260
 
NR360 Information Systems in Healthcare Team Technology Pr.docx
NR360 Information Systems in Healthcare Team Technology Pr.docxNR360 Information Systems in Healthcare Team Technology Pr.docx
NR360 Information Systems in Healthcare Team Technology Pr.docx
henrymartin15260
 
NR443 Guidelines for Caring for PopulationsMilestone 2 Assess.docx
NR443 Guidelines for Caring for PopulationsMilestone 2 Assess.docxNR443 Guidelines for Caring for PopulationsMilestone 2 Assess.docx
NR443 Guidelines for Caring for PopulationsMilestone 2 Assess.docx
henrymartin15260
 
Nowak Aesthetics, was founded by Dr. Eugene Nowak in 1999, in Ch.docx
Nowak Aesthetics, was founded by Dr. Eugene Nowak in 1999, in Ch.docxNowak Aesthetics, was founded by Dr. Eugene Nowak in 1999, in Ch.docx
Nowak Aesthetics, was founded by Dr. Eugene Nowak in 1999, in Ch.docx
henrymartin15260
 
NR305 Health Assessment Course Project Milestone #2 Nursing Di.docx
NR305 Health Assessment Course Project Milestone #2 Nursing Di.docxNR305 Health Assessment Course Project Milestone #2 Nursing Di.docx
NR305 Health Assessment Course Project Milestone #2 Nursing Di.docx
henrymartin15260
 
Nova Southeastern University H. Wayne Huizenga School of Busin.docx
Nova Southeastern University H. Wayne Huizenga School of Busin.docxNova Southeastern University H. Wayne Huizenga School of Busin.docx
Nova Southeastern University H. Wayne Huizenga School of Busin.docx
henrymartin15260
 

More from henrymartin15260 (20)

NT2580 Week 1 Understanding IT Infrastructure Security An.docx
NT2580 Week 1 Understanding IT Infrastructure Security An.docxNT2580 Week 1 Understanding IT Infrastructure Security An.docx
NT2580 Week 1 Understanding IT Infrastructure Security An.docx
 
NTC362 Week 3OSI Model, Switching Systems, Network Channel Pr.docx
NTC362   Week 3OSI Model, Switching Systems, Network Channel Pr.docxNTC362   Week 3OSI Model, Switching Systems, Network Channel Pr.docx
NTC362 Week 3OSI Model, Switching Systems, Network Channel Pr.docx
 
NT2580 Week 4 Hardening a NetworkAnalysis 4.2Availability, In.docx
NT2580 Week 4 Hardening a NetworkAnalysis 4.2Availability, In.docxNT2580 Week 4 Hardening a NetworkAnalysis 4.2Availability, In.docx
NT2580 Week 4 Hardening a NetworkAnalysis 4.2Availability, In.docx
 
NTNU, May 2009 ntnu.nocbm 1 LEARNING AND MEMORY .docx
NTNU, May 2009 ntnu.nocbm 1 LEARNING AND MEMORY .docxNTNU, May 2009 ntnu.nocbm 1 LEARNING AND MEMORY .docx
NTNU, May 2009 ntnu.nocbm 1 LEARNING AND MEMORY .docx
 
nowHow to be Army StrongI was 18 years old when I saw my fa.docx
nowHow to be Army StrongI was 18 years old when I saw my fa.docxnowHow to be Army StrongI was 18 years old when I saw my fa.docx
nowHow to be Army StrongI was 18 years old when I saw my fa.docx
 
NR-351 Transitions in Professional NursingWebsite Evaluation T.docx
NR-351 Transitions in Professional NursingWebsite Evaluation T.docxNR-351 Transitions in Professional NursingWebsite Evaluation T.docx
NR-351 Transitions in Professional NursingWebsite Evaluation T.docx
 
Ntc 362 Week 2, Integrative Network Design Project , Part 1By Alucar.docx
Ntc 362 Week 2, Integrative Network Design Project , Part 1By Alucar.docxNtc 362 Week 2, Integrative Network Design Project , Part 1By Alucar.docx
Ntc 362 Week 2, Integrative Network Design Project , Part 1By Alucar.docx
 
NTHEMIND OF GREATCOMPANIESBy Scott BlanchardThe.docx
NTHEMIND OF GREATCOMPANIESBy Scott BlanchardThe.docxNTHEMIND OF GREATCOMPANIESBy Scott BlanchardThe.docx
NTHEMIND OF GREATCOMPANIESBy Scott BlanchardThe.docx
 
NSG6001 Advanced Practice Nursing I Page 1 of 5 © 2007 S.docx
NSG6001 Advanced Practice Nursing I Page 1 of 5 © 2007 S.docxNSG6001 Advanced Practice Nursing I Page 1 of 5 © 2007 S.docx
NSG6001 Advanced Practice Nursing I Page 1 of 5 © 2007 S.docx
 
NR360 We Can But Dare We.docx Revised 5 ‐ 9 .docx
NR360   We   Can   But   Dare   We.docx   Revised   5 ‐ 9 .docxNR360   We   Can   But   Dare   We.docx   Revised   5 ‐ 9 .docx
NR360 We Can But Dare We.docx Revised 5 ‐ 9 .docx
 
ns;,eilrlt.lnterviewing is one HR function.docx
ns;,eilrlt.lnterviewing is one HR function.docxns;,eilrlt.lnterviewing is one HR function.docx
ns;,eilrlt.lnterviewing is one HR function.docx
 
NR443 Guidelines for Caring for PopulationsMilestone 2 As.docx
NR443 Guidelines for Caring for PopulationsMilestone 2 As.docxNR443 Guidelines for Caring for PopulationsMilestone 2 As.docx
NR443 Guidelines for Caring for PopulationsMilestone 2 As.docx
 
NRB Dec’99 1WHITHER THE EMERGENCY MANAGER 1Neil R Bri.docx
NRB Dec’99 1WHITHER THE EMERGENCY MANAGER 1Neil R Bri.docxNRB Dec’99 1WHITHER THE EMERGENCY MANAGER 1Neil R Bri.docx
NRB Dec’99 1WHITHER THE EMERGENCY MANAGER 1Neil R Bri.docx
 
Now, its time to create that treasure map to hide the treasur.docx
Now, its time to create that treasure map to hide the treasur.docxNow, its time to create that treasure map to hide the treasur.docx
Now, its time to create that treasure map to hide the treasur.docx
 
NR361 Information Systems in HealthcareInterview with a Nursing.docx
NR361 Information Systems in HealthcareInterview with a Nursing.docxNR361 Information Systems in HealthcareInterview with a Nursing.docx
NR361 Information Systems in HealthcareInterview with a Nursing.docx
 
NR360 Information Systems in Healthcare Team Technology Pr.docx
NR360 Information Systems in Healthcare Team Technology Pr.docxNR360 Information Systems in Healthcare Team Technology Pr.docx
NR360 Information Systems in Healthcare Team Technology Pr.docx
 
NR443 Guidelines for Caring for PopulationsMilestone 2 Assess.docx
NR443 Guidelines for Caring for PopulationsMilestone 2 Assess.docxNR443 Guidelines for Caring for PopulationsMilestone 2 Assess.docx
NR443 Guidelines for Caring for PopulationsMilestone 2 Assess.docx
 
Nowak Aesthetics, was founded by Dr. Eugene Nowak in 1999, in Ch.docx
Nowak Aesthetics, was founded by Dr. Eugene Nowak in 1999, in Ch.docxNowak Aesthetics, was founded by Dr. Eugene Nowak in 1999, in Ch.docx
Nowak Aesthetics, was founded by Dr. Eugene Nowak in 1999, in Ch.docx
 
NR305 Health Assessment Course Project Milestone #2 Nursing Di.docx
NR305 Health Assessment Course Project Milestone #2 Nursing Di.docxNR305 Health Assessment Course Project Milestone #2 Nursing Di.docx
NR305 Health Assessment Course Project Milestone #2 Nursing Di.docx
 
Nova Southeastern University H. Wayne Huizenga School of Busin.docx
Nova Southeastern University H. Wayne Huizenga School of Busin.docxNova Southeastern University H. Wayne Huizenga School of Busin.docx
Nova Southeastern University H. Wayne Huizenga School of Busin.docx
 

Recently uploaded

The basics of sentences session 2pptx copy.pptx
The basics of sentences session 2pptx copy.pptxThe basics of sentences session 2pptx copy.pptx
The basics of sentences session 2pptx copy.pptx
heathfieldcps1
 
Gardella_PRCampaignConclusion Pitch Letter
Gardella_PRCampaignConclusion Pitch LetterGardella_PRCampaignConclusion Pitch Letter
Gardella_PRCampaignConclusion Pitch Letter
MateoGardella
 
Making and Justifying Mathematical Decisions.pdf
Making and Justifying Mathematical Decisions.pdfMaking and Justifying Mathematical Decisions.pdf
Making and Justifying Mathematical Decisions.pdf
Chris Hunter
 
1029 - Danh muc Sach Giao Khoa 10 . pdf
1029 -  Danh muc Sach Giao Khoa 10 . pdf1029 -  Danh muc Sach Giao Khoa 10 . pdf
1029 - Danh muc Sach Giao Khoa 10 . pdf
QucHHunhnh
 
1029-Danh muc Sach Giao Khoa khoi 6.pdf
1029-Danh muc Sach Giao Khoa khoi  6.pdf1029-Danh muc Sach Giao Khoa khoi  6.pdf
1029-Danh muc Sach Giao Khoa khoi 6.pdf
QucHHunhnh
 

Recently uploaded (20)

Ecological Succession. ( ECOSYSTEM, B. Pharmacy, 1st Year, Sem-II, Environmen...
Ecological Succession. ( ECOSYSTEM, B. Pharmacy, 1st Year, Sem-II, Environmen...Ecological Succession. ( ECOSYSTEM, B. Pharmacy, 1st Year, Sem-II, Environmen...
Ecological Succession. ( ECOSYSTEM, B. Pharmacy, 1st Year, Sem-II, Environmen...
 
PROCESS RECORDING FORMAT.docx
PROCESS      RECORDING        FORMAT.docxPROCESS      RECORDING        FORMAT.docx
PROCESS RECORDING FORMAT.docx
 
Web & Social Media Analytics Previous Year Question Paper.pdf
Web & Social Media Analytics Previous Year Question Paper.pdfWeb & Social Media Analytics Previous Year Question Paper.pdf
Web & Social Media Analytics Previous Year Question Paper.pdf
 
fourth grading exam for kindergarten in writing
fourth grading exam for kindergarten in writingfourth grading exam for kindergarten in writing
fourth grading exam for kindergarten in writing
 
The basics of sentences session 2pptx copy.pptx
The basics of sentences session 2pptx copy.pptxThe basics of sentences session 2pptx copy.pptx
The basics of sentences session 2pptx copy.pptx
 
SOCIAL AND HISTORICAL CONTEXT - LFTVD.pptx
SOCIAL AND HISTORICAL CONTEXT - LFTVD.pptxSOCIAL AND HISTORICAL CONTEXT - LFTVD.pptx
SOCIAL AND HISTORICAL CONTEXT - LFTVD.pptx
 
Class 11th Physics NEET formula sheet pdf
Class 11th Physics NEET formula sheet pdfClass 11th Physics NEET formula sheet pdf
Class 11th Physics NEET formula sheet pdf
 
Mehran University Newsletter Vol-X, Issue-I, 2024
Mehran University Newsletter Vol-X, Issue-I, 2024Mehran University Newsletter Vol-X, Issue-I, 2024
Mehran University Newsletter Vol-X, Issue-I, 2024
 
Gardella_PRCampaignConclusion Pitch Letter
Gardella_PRCampaignConclusion Pitch LetterGardella_PRCampaignConclusion Pitch Letter
Gardella_PRCampaignConclusion Pitch Letter
 
SECOND SEMESTER TOPIC COVERAGE SY 2023-2024 Trends, Networks, and Critical Th...
SECOND SEMESTER TOPIC COVERAGE SY 2023-2024 Trends, Networks, and Critical Th...SECOND SEMESTER TOPIC COVERAGE SY 2023-2024 Trends, Networks, and Critical Th...
SECOND SEMESTER TOPIC COVERAGE SY 2023-2024 Trends, Networks, and Critical Th...
 
This PowerPoint helps students to consider the concept of infinity.
This PowerPoint helps students to consider the concept of infinity.This PowerPoint helps students to consider the concept of infinity.
This PowerPoint helps students to consider the concept of infinity.
 
Explore beautiful and ugly buildings. Mathematics helps us create beautiful d...
Explore beautiful and ugly buildings. Mathematics helps us create beautiful d...Explore beautiful and ugly buildings. Mathematics helps us create beautiful d...
Explore beautiful and ugly buildings. Mathematics helps us create beautiful d...
 
Holdier Curriculum Vitae (April 2024).pdf
Holdier Curriculum Vitae (April 2024).pdfHoldier Curriculum Vitae (April 2024).pdf
Holdier Curriculum Vitae (April 2024).pdf
 
Making and Justifying Mathematical Decisions.pdf
Making and Justifying Mathematical Decisions.pdfMaking and Justifying Mathematical Decisions.pdf
Making and Justifying Mathematical Decisions.pdf
 
1029 - Danh muc Sach Giao Khoa 10 . pdf
1029 -  Danh muc Sach Giao Khoa 10 . pdf1029 -  Danh muc Sach Giao Khoa 10 . pdf
1029 - Danh muc Sach Giao Khoa 10 . pdf
 
1029-Danh muc Sach Giao Khoa khoi 6.pdf
1029-Danh muc Sach Giao Khoa khoi  6.pdf1029-Danh muc Sach Giao Khoa khoi  6.pdf
1029-Danh muc Sach Giao Khoa khoi 6.pdf
 
microwave assisted reaction. General introduction
microwave assisted reaction. General introductionmicrowave assisted reaction. General introduction
microwave assisted reaction. General introduction
 
Nutritional Needs Presentation - HLTH 104
Nutritional Needs Presentation - HLTH 104Nutritional Needs Presentation - HLTH 104
Nutritional Needs Presentation - HLTH 104
 
Accessible design: Minimum effort, maximum impact
Accessible design: Minimum effort, maximum impactAccessible design: Minimum effort, maximum impact
Accessible design: Minimum effort, maximum impact
 
Mattingly "AI & Prompt Design: Structured Data, Assistants, & RAG"
Mattingly "AI & Prompt Design: Structured Data, Assistants, & RAG"Mattingly "AI & Prompt Design: Structured Data, Assistants, & RAG"
Mattingly "AI & Prompt Design: Structured Data, Assistants, & RAG"
 

nR E E 693 5T o c o m p l e t e th i s e x a m y o u n.docx

  • 1. n R E E 693 5 T o c o m p l e t e th i s e x a m y o u n e e d t o a n s w e r 8 q u e s t i o n l i s t e d b e lo w . T h e f i r s t t w o q u e s t i o n s a r e t o b e a n s w e r e d i n E x c e l u s i n g th e a s s o c ia t e d t a b s i n c l u d e d o n t h e e x a m R E E 6935 t h a t i s p r o v i d e d t o y o u q u e s t i o n 3 - 8 a r e t o b e a n s w e r e d o n a Wo r d D o c u m e n t i n t h e o r d e r i n w h ic h t h e y a p p e a r . D u e A p r i l 28 , 2015 . 1. ) (9 P o i n t s ) U s i n g t h e d a t a p r o v i d e d t o y o u i n t h e P r o b l e m 1 t a b , c a lc u la t e t h e r e q u e s t e d v a l u e s a n d i n c l u d e y o u r a n s w e r i n th e i r r e s p e c t i v e c e l ls h i gh l ig h t e d i n y e l lo w . 2 . ) (10 P o i n t ) T h e t a b la b e l e d P r o b l e m 2 i n c l u d e s m o n t h ly p r i c e d a t a o n th e SA P 500 (SPY ) a s w e l l a s o n K B H o m e (K B H , a r e a l e s t a t e d e v e lo p m e n t c o m p a n y ) a n d o n H o m e P r o p e r t i e s I n c . (H M E , a n d e q u i t y R E I T s p e c ia l i z e s i n a p a r tm e n t r e n t a ls ) . U s i
  • 2. n g r e g r e s s i o n c a l c u l a t e t h e B e t a o f e a c h o f t h e s e 2 r e a l e s t a t e c o m p a n ie s f o r t h e f u l l t im e p e r i o d p r o v id e d t o y o u . a . D is p l a y y o u r c a l c u l a t e d B e t a s i n t h e c e ll s h i g h l igh t e d i n y e l l o w . Y o u m a y i n c l u d e y o u r f u l l r e g r e s s i o n r e s u l t s i n t w o o th e r s e p a r a t e t a b s b . W h i c h c o m p a n y h a s a h i g h e r B e t a ? I n o n e t o tw o s e n t e n c e s e x p l a i n w h y y o u d id o r d i d n ' t e x p e c t t h a t c o m p a n y t o b e a s s o c ia t e d w i t h a h ig h e r B e t a . 3 . (10 P o i n t s ) P l e a s e r e f e r t o t h e p a p e r t it l e d O n t h e R e la t i o n b e t w e e n L o c a l A m e n i t ie s a n d H o u s i n g P r ic e C h a n g e s " p r o v i d e d t o y o u w i t h t h i s e x a m a n d a n s w e r t h e f o l lo w i n g q u e s t io n s . a . B r i e f ly e x p l a i n w h a t w e c a n l e a r n f r o m F ig u r e 2 ? A r e t h e s e r e s u l t s e x p e c t e d ? Wh y ?
  • 3. b . B r i e f ly e x p l a i n w h a t w e c a n l e a r n f r o m f i g u r e 4? A r e t h e s e r e s u l t s e x p e c t e d ? W hy ? c . B r i e f ly e x p l a i n w h a t w e c a n l e a r n f r o m t h e r e g r e s s i o n r e s u l t s p r e s e n t e d i n c o l u m n (4) o f t a b l e 4 . H o w t h e s e r e s u lt s a r e d if f e r e n t f r o m t h e r e s u l t s p r e s e n t e d i n c o l u m n (2) o f t a b le 4? d . B r i e f l y e x p l a i n w h a t w e c a n l e a r n f r o m t a b l e 6 t h a t w e d o n ' t a l r e a d y k n o w f r o m t h e r e s u l t s p r e s e n t e d i n t h e p r e v i o u s t a b l e s . NEATPAGEINFO:id=C46A481D-C837-496A-BF88- 1036B1B658D9 NEATPAGEINFO:id=1C69E900-548F-4525-A8FC- 241D36019B8E NEATPAGEINFO:id=FFE7D9CB-237F-4EF0-A0CE- 1E8CE4F89D7D
  • 4. NEATPAGEINFO:id=D3925A9E-2F11-486E-BE0D- F7BAD671A14E On the Relation between Local Amenities and Housing Price Changes Eli Beracha, Ph.D. Hollo School of Real Estate, Florida International University Benjamin T. Gilbert, Ph.D. Department of Economics and Finance, University of Wyoming Tyler Kjorstad Department of Economics and Finance, University of Wyoming Kiplan S. Womack, Ph.D. Belk College of Business, UNC Charlotte Abstract This paper explores the extent to which local amenities are related to housing price volatility and appreciation in different US cities. Using total amenity values constructed by Albouy (2009), we
  • 5. find that cities with higher amenity values experience greater housing price appreciation along with higher price volatility. These empirical results are inline with the land leverage hypothesis presented by Bostic, et al. (2007) and are also supported by our theoretical model, which shows that variations in long run anticipated income affect households’ willingness to pay for the physical attributes as well as amenities of housing. Our results are shown to be symmetrical across up and down markets and are robust to a series of robustness tests, such as regional and land supply elasticity controls. Keywords: house prices, volatility, amenities, land leverage JEL codes: R00, R14, R21, R31 Introduction Over the last few decades housing rate of price appreciation and price volatility varied in a material way across different locations. Housing is not only the
  • 6. largest single asset held by most American households1, but also represent a concentrated, levered and undiversified financial exposure for many of them. Moreover, housing value and volatility play an increasingly important role in the performance of a progressively integrated broad economy, as it was most evident during the housing boom of the early 2000’s and the “great recession” that followed. Therefore, exploring factors that may explain variations in housing value is warranted. This paper examines the extent to which housing price volatility and rate of appreciation are related to the local amenities that accompany the physical characteristics of housing in a large sample of US locations. At any given location land and its associated amenities is limited in supply and non-reproducible. In contrast, improvements can be reproduced in greater supply elsewhere and experience physical and functional obsolescence over time. This implies that supply and demand shocks in the local economy are expected to be capitalized into land values, not the structure. As a result, higher housing price volatility is
  • 7. predicted in areas where the value of locational amenities is high and these areas should also appreciate at a faster pace in an overall growing economy. This line of reasoning is similar to the land leverage hypothesis that is presented by Bostic, Longhofer and Redfearn (2007) and investigated in the recent literature. Evidence from our empirical analysis show a positive and robust relation between housing price volatility and amenity value. Additionally, a positive relation that is statistically and economically significant between housing price appreciation and amenities is also illustrated. However, when the relation between risk-adjusted price appreciation and amenities is examined, 1 Based on U.S. Census Bureau, Survey of Income and Program Participation the results are dependent on whether risk-adjusted price appreciation is measured in absolute terms or relative to the performance of the general housing market. Overall, the empirical results of our analysis support our theoretical model and hypotheses.
  • 8. We takes advantage of a set of three land value proxies, namely Quality of Life, Trade- Productivity and Total Amenity values, in order to provide evidence on the relation between land values and changes in housing prices for a broad sample of cities. Our paper makes several contributions to the existing literature. First, we show that the value of amenities can proxy for the value of land share, which is difficult to estimate mainly due to data availability. Amenity value and land share are also shown to have similar relation with supply constraints that the literature finds to be important when determining real estate price movements and trends (Glaeser, Gyourko and Saiz (2008), for example). Second, for a large sample of cities we provide evidence of positive relation not only between amenities and housing price volatility, but also between amenities and housing price appreciation. To our knowledge, our study is the first attempt to explore both of these links. Moreover, we provide evidence on the relation between amenities and risk-adjusted housing appreciation in absolute and relative terms. Third, and lastly, we are the first to document
  • 9. symmetry in the relation between amenities and housing price performance in up and down markets as well as the robustness of this relation to supply constraints and other locational controls. We believe that our paper enhances the understanding of how local amenities are relate to changes in housing values. A better understanding of this relation is an important issue, not just for the individual home owner, but also for investors, lenders, and tax collectors and hence may also have policy implications. Literature Review Developed streams of literature explore the relation between specific local amenities (or disamenities) and housing prices. Examples of housing related amenities investigated in these studies include school quality (Black (1999) and Bogart and Cromwell (2000), among many others), proximity to the ocean and ocean view (Landry and Hindsley (2011) and Wyman,
  • 10. Hutchinson and Tiwari (2014), for example), susceptibility to flood hazard (Turnbullm, Zahirovic- Hebert and Mothorpe (2013)), and many more. Because these studies predominantly focus on a the effect of a specific amenity on housing values at the local level they are not directly relate to our study, which examines the relation between a broad set of amenities on housing performance a across different cities and regions. The stream of literature that is most closely related to our research includes papers that explore land values and study the land leverage hypothesis. Davis and Palumbo (2007) construct a database that distinguishes between the value of residential land and structures for 46 large US metropolitan areas. The authors report that the average value of land relative to the value of structures experienced a material increase over the 1984 – 2004 time period, which implies that future rate of housing price appreciation and volatility are likely to increasingly be determined by demand factors. In their paper, the authors find substantial regional variation in land share. In 2004,
  • 11. land share was estimated to comprise 74% of value for homes in the West Coast, which is more than double the Midwest share of 36%. Similarly, Albouy and Ehrlich (2012) find that land share varies from 11% to 48% with a national average of 37%.2 In regards to appreciation, nationally 2 The estimates from Davis and Palumbo (2007) are based on a residual method (difference between total property value and the estimated value of the structure) whereas the estimates from Albouy and Ehrlich (2012) are transaction- based from land sales across the U.S. The latter study points out that their estimates are generally lower than that of the former study and that this is likely due to the methodological differences. In a later study Albouy and Ehrlich (2013) analyze land values from transactions across the U.S. and find that the strongest predictor of value per acre is lot size, followed by location, and then time. from 1984 to 2004. Davis and Palumbo (2007) estimate that land appreciated 204% while the structure appreciated 19%. This level of land appreciation is consistent with the estimates from the national-level transaction based land price index of Sirmans and
  • 12. Slade (2012) and the MSA-level transaction based land price index of Nichols, Oliner and Mulhall (2013). Bostic, Longhofer and Redfearn (2006) investigate the relationship between land leverage and land taxation regimes. The study finds that the growth in land values is more volatile than growth in overall property value, which means that higher land leveraged metropolitan areas have higher overall property value growth volatility.3 In an earlier study, Dolde and Tirtiroglu (2002) investigate volatility shifts in regional house price changes and find that the vast majority of “volatility events” are purely regional, rather than national, in nature. Similarly, Miao, Ramchander and Simpson (2011) find linkages of returns and volatility within geographic regions. On a more local level, Bostic, Longhofer and Redfearn (2007) refer to the land leverage hypothesis when examine prices of land and improvement in Wichita, Kansas. Bostic Longhofer and Refearn highlights the importance of this property price decomposition for better understanding of prices of the real estate markets. Paciorek (2013) examines the relation between
  • 13. housing volatility and regulation of new housing supply. Paciorek illustrate how more regulation lowers the elasticity of new housing supply by increasing the lags in the permit process and adding to the cost of supplying new houses on the margin. These regulations anlong with geographic limitations lead to less investment, on average. Paciorek then links his findings to illustrate that stricter regulation combined with geographic limitations decrease the responsiveness of investment to demand shocks and hence amplify volatility in property prices. Kok, Monkkonen and Quigley (2014) also examined the effect of local land use regulations and find that they are 3 Haurin and Zhou (2010) provide an excellent summary of the determinants of house price volatility. closely linked to the value of houses sold. Focusing on the San Francisco Bay Area, the authors find this link to be particularly strong because regulations in that area are so pervasive and land values represent a large fraction of house values.
  • 14. Theory and Hypothesis Development In this section we develop hypotheses about the relationship between local amenities and home price volatility. We use a standard hedonic price model to derive predictions about volatility and risk-adjusted returns that arise from variation in macroeconomic fundamentals that might alter a household’s expectations of permanent income. Specifically, we show that (1) home price volatility is unambiguously greater in housing markets with more amenities, and (2) amenities have a theoretically ambiguous effect on risk-adjusted returns because of the tradeoff between the capitalization of growing amenity values in home prices as incomes rise, and the unambiguous increase in volatility due to amenities. Consider a typical formulation of the hedonic price equation: ����� = �0� + ∑ ��� ���� � �=1 + ��� �� + ���
  • 15. (I) where ����� is the natural log of home prices in market i at time t, ���� are a set of J home characteristics (e.g., square footage, lot size, etc.) and �� is the level of amenities that homebuyers have access to in that market. This can be considered, for example, an approximation to the locus of bid-ask tangency points in price-attribute space as shown by Rosen (1974) where ��� captures approximation error and other iid unobserved local shocks to prices. The value of home characteristics in a market may vary over time to capture trends in physical property improvements or changes in valuation of those characteristics because of income or preferences, The level of amenities captures more stable variables like proximity to coastline and average climate and is therefore fixed. Notice, however, that we allow the coefficients to vary with time, which is a natural way to allow the contribution of each attribute in overall price to depend on time-varying macroeconomic conditions. In order to decompose the overall
  • 16. price volatility into a home-value component and an amenity component, define ��� as the “base” price based on home characteristics only: ����� = �0� + ∑ ��� ���� � �=1 Consider the following process for base home price appreciation: ����� = ����,�−1 + �� + ��� , ��� ~���(0, �� 2 ) Here we allow base home prices to grow at a stable average growth rate �� reflecting long-run macroeconomic or permanent income growth, subject to idiosyncratic short-run macroeconomic shocks ��� . For simplicity, we restrict growth rates to be equal across local markets. Allowing market-specific growth by explicitly specifying processes for �0� , ��� , and ���� comes at the expense of unnecessary algebraic complexity without changing
  • 17. the qualitative results or providing any additional understanding of the intuition. In the present formulation, temporal variation in real estate prices is driven by purely macroeconomic changes. This allows us to isolate the relationship of amenities with price volatility. We can now rewrite (I) as the sum of the logged base price and the contribution of amenities: ����� = ����� + ��� �� + ��� (I’) In this formulation, ��� is a semi-elasticity which captures the percentage difference in a home’s value due to a difference in the level of local amenities. We consider two cases for the ��� process: Case A: ��� = �� + ��� , ��� ~���(0, �� 2). (IIA) Case B: ��� = �� + ��,�−1 + ��� , ��� ~���(0, �� 2). (IIB) In Case A, we give this parameter a stationary distribution to capture the possibility that the proportional contribution of a local amenity to a home’s value is high during positive
  • 18. macroeconomic shocks and vice versa, and varies around a fixed mean. In Case B, we consider the case in which the amenity contribution increases as permanent incomes increase with economic growth. This second case implies that not only home prices, but home price appreciation is greater in areas with more amenities. The vector of annual shocks to base home values and amenity values � = (��� , ��� ) � has the (2X2) covariance matrix �: � = [ �� 2 ��� ��� �� 2 ] Where ��� > 0 captures the possibility that both sources of temporal home price variation are driven by common macroeconomic or housing market shocks. Subtracting ����,�−1 from �����, it is straightforward to obtain
  • 19. �� ��� ��,�−1 = �� ��� ��,�−1 + (��� − ��,�−1)�� + (��� − ��,�−1) which we can rewrite as ���� = ��� + Δ��� �� + Δ��� (III) where ���� is the growth in actual home prices in market i and ��� is the growth in base home prices between periods t-1 and t. We can show the effects of amenities on volatility and risk- adjusted returns using either the straightforward calculation of volatility and the Sharpe Ratio, or by specifying a capital asset pricing model (CAPM) for residential real estate and examining the asset Beta (�) and Jensen’s Alpha (�) for market i relative to the U.S. housing price index. The Effect of Amenities on Home Price Volatility
  • 20. Taking the expectation of (III) in the two cases gives, Case A: �(���� ) = �� (IVA) Case B: �(����) = �� + ���� (IVB) which will be used in the calculation of both volatility and the Beta (�) for market i, and in the derivation of risk-adjusted returns. Taking the square root of the variance of (III) will provide an expression for how home price volatility is affected by the level of amenities. This expression is given by Case A: √���(����) = ��� = √�� 2 + 2�� 2�A 2 + 2�� ��� + 2�� 2 (VA) Case B: √���(���� ) = ��� = √�� 2 + �� 2�A 2 + 2�� ��� + 2�� 2
  • 21. (VB) In both cases this will be an unambiguously positive function of amenities as long as the home- attribute valuation and amenity valuation drivers do not systematically move in opposite directions. This is unlikely because these drivers are common macroeconomic shocks, so the covariance term under the radical will be nonnegative. The CAPM for residential real estate, explained in more detail in the Methodology section, can be thought of as a regression of housing price growth in an individual market on growth in the U.S. Housing Price Index, as in ���� = �� + �� ��� + ��� Where ��� is the growth in the U.S. Housing Price Index, and ��� is a mean-zero regression error. Because ��� is the growth in an index that summarizes prices across all markets, we can write it as ��� = ��� + Δ��� �̅� + Δ��̅�
  • 22. The Beta for housing assets in market i is simply �� = ���(����,���) ���(���) , which in the two cases reduces to: Case A: �� = �� 2 + �̅���� + �� (��� + 2�̅��� 2) �� 2 + 2�̅���� + 2�̅� 2 �� 2 (VIA) Case B: �� = �� 2 + �̅���� + �� (��� + �̅��� 2) �� 2 + 2�̅���� + �̅�
  • 23. 2�� 2 (VIB) In either case, once again this is an unambiguously increasing function of amenities in market i. Hence, we hypothesize the following: H1: All other things equal, the magnitude of real estate price fluctuations (volatility) in a particular location and the amenity value associate with that location are positively related. The Effect of Amenities on Risk-Adjusted Returns Next we consider whether we should expect residential property investors to be compensated with greater risk-adjusted returns for the additional risks posed by the increased volatility, or whether we should expect homebuyers to accept additional risk for a given return in order to enjoy the amenity. We first evaluate this question using the Sharpe Ratio, followed by an examination of Jensen’s Alpha from the CAPM model. In our context the Sharpe Ratio can be
  • 24. written as ��� = �(����) ��� (VI) We have already seen that ��� is an increasing function of amenities, and now we must show whether expected price growth is increasing in amenities by enough to offset the denominator. From (IVA), we know that in Case A the numerator of the Sharpe Ratio does not depend on amenities. Therefore, in this case risk-adjusted returns decline with amenities. This is intuitive for Case A because although amenities are a component of price levels, they do not contribute to home price appreciation and only add volatility to the behavior of prices over time. As we will show in the empirical section, however, U.S. home price appreciation is significantly positively related to amenities, suggesting that
  • 25. Case B may be more relevant empirically. We can see from (IVB) that home price appreciation and price levels increase with amenity levels. The question is now whether the effect of �� in appreciation outweighs the increased volatility in calculation of risk-adjusted returns. Using the chain rule, ��� ��� = ����� − 1 2 ��� (2�� �� 2 + ��� ) ��� 2 (VII) The sign of this expression hinges on a mean-variance tradeoff in the amenity contribution to the overall home price process. It can be shown using (VB) and (VI) that the sign is more likely to be positive when �� is large relative to ��, ��
  • 26. 2 is relatively small, and �� 2 is relatively large. In other words, if the amenity contribution to price growth has a low variance but a high mean relative to the appreciation in base prices, then risk-adjusted returns are more likely to be higher in markets with high amenities. Likewise, if base home price appreciation has relatively low variance, adding additional volatility from amenities without much additional price appreciation to accompany it can drive down risk-adjusted returns. A similar mean-variance tradeoff arises in Jensen’s Alpha, although because Jensen’s Alpha for a single market is measured relative to the broader U.S. residential real estate market, whereas the Sharpe Ratio is an absolute measure, the two quantities need not produce the same outcome. In our context Jensen’s Alpha is defined as �� = �(���� ) − �� �(��� ) In Case A, this collapses to �� = (1 − �� )��, which is unambiguously decreasing in amenities as
  • 27. �� increases in amenities, again because in Case A amenities do not affect raw home price returns. In Case B, amenities contribute to housing price appreciation directly in addition to adding to volatility. This a tradeoff in Jensen’s Alpha is �� = �� + ���� − �� (�� + ���̅�) Taking the derivative with respect to �� and simplifying yields ��� ��� = ��(�� 2 + �̅���� ) − �� (��� + �̅��� 2) �� 2 + 2�̅���� + �̅� 2�� 2 (VIII) Similar to the Sharpe Ratio, equation (VIII) shows that if amenities make a low-mean and high- variance contribution to price appreciation, relative to the mean and variance of base price
  • 28. appreciation, then risk adjusted returns will be lower in cities with high amenity values (and vice versa). Unlike the Sharpe Ratio, however, because Alpha is a relative measure, the sign of (VIII) also depends on the broader U.S. market average amenity contribution to growth �̅�. In particular, if �̅� is relatively large then the volatility of amenity values �� 2 has a bigger negative effect on returns in market i relative to the broader market. In other words, if amenities are a large share of overall market growth (rather than in just a few individual markets), then volatility in amenity values take a bigger toll on risk-adjusted returns. In the remainder of the paper we evaluate each of these relationships empirically. Data We construct the dataset analyzed in this paper from a few different sources. The dependent variable in this study is a measure of housing price volatility in different Metropolitan Statistical Areas (MSAs) across the US. This variable is calculated (as we describe in the methodology
  • 29. section) from the series of Housing Price Index (HPI) that are published by the Federal Housing Finance Agency (FHFA). The FHFA publishes an HPI for just over 400 MSAs with quarterly frequency beginning as early as the first quarter of 1975 for some MSAs. We take advantage of the length of these series and examine the Q1 1975 through Q3 2013 time period in this study. The HPI for each MSA is also used in order to calculate the rate of housing appreciation and segmentation of the data into up and down pricing trend periods. Our main independent variables of interest are the values associated with the metropolitans’ total amenity value, which are extracted from Albouy (2009). In Albouy (2009) the author also estimates values for the quality of life and trade- productivity, which are included in the estimation of the total amenity values. Albouy estimates these values for 241 MSAs across the US.4 Table 1 reports these values for the top and bottom five metro areas in terms of total amenities,
  • 30. quality of life and trade productivity in order to give the reader a sense for these values.5 The San Francisco-Oakland-San Jose MSA is topping the list with total amenity value of 0.323 while McAllen-Edinburg-Mission is at the bottom of the list with a total amenity value of -0.225. Additionally, Table 1 shows that MSAs with high amenity value are also associate with high trade- productivity and quality of life values and vice versa. This is not surprising given that Albouy constructs the total amenity value from the trade-productivity and quality of life values. Because our study focuses on the relation between housing price volatility and amenity values rather than the establishment of these values, we employs Albouy’s estimates at their face value without making an attempt to improve, change or challenge them. For brevity, we also don’t discuss the 4 Glaser, Saiz and Summers (2008) use amenity variables (individual measures, not index-based) to control for housing demand in models of house price appreciation and construction permits. The authors note that while these variables don’t change over time, demand for them might have, so they provide a natural way of controlling for changes in
  • 31. demand. 5 A full list of the 241 metropolitans and their respective amenity, trade-productivity and quality of life values can be found in Albouy (2009). methodology used in Albouy (2009) to estimate these values and interested readers are encouraged to refer to the original paper. Albouy (2009) notes that other directly observed variables that are used in the literature in order to characterize and distinguish between different locations are associated with overall amenity value. Therefore, we make an effort to collect some of the commonly used area characteristics to determine whether Albouy’s estimates are superior proxies when explaining housing price volatilities. These area characteristics include land supply elasticity, education, weather and proximity to recreational water. A widely used measure for land availability is the land supply elasticity (LSE) measure by Albert Saiz. Originally, Saiz (2010) published LSE estimates for 95 large US cities, but since then Saiz expanded the availability of the estimates to 269 US
  • 32. cities.6 These values range between 0.60 and 12.14 for Miami, FL where available land is scarce and for Pine Bluff, AR where available land is plentiful, respectively. Since Saiz’s measures are available at the city rather than the MSA level, we use a weighted average that is based on cities population to construct a LSE value for the MSAs in our sample. We refer to the United States Census Bureau for statistics on cities’ population and record the 2010 population estimate for each city in our dataset. Values for cities’ education level are also extracted from the Census Bureau and are based on 5-year estimates of the American Community Survey. Specifically, we use the percentage of the population over the age of 25 with a Bachelor degree or higher as our education proxy. Increase in the supply of college graduates increases local wages directly and indirectly via a spillover effect 6 Glaeser and Gyourko (2003), Glaeser, Gyourko and Saks (2005), Saiz (2010), Paciorek (2013), and Kok, Monkkonen and Quigley (2014) collectively find that inelastic land supply and zoning restrictions and regulation (measured as lags in the permit process, increasing the number of permit
  • 33. reviews) in urban areas amplify house price volatility by creating scarcity, increasing the time to develop and adding costs of supplying new houses. Grimes and Aitken (2010) show that this effect is not domestic in nature when exploring housing price dynamics in New Zealand. that impacts the wages of local non-college graduates (Moretti (2004) and Rosenthal and Strange (2008), for example). For general weather information we first refer to the National Oceanic Atmospheric as a source7 from which we gather the value for the average percentage of sunshine per day in each city included in our database. Unfortunately, the NOAA only provides estimates of this value for 115 of the 238 MSAs in our sample. As alternative weather proxies that are available for more MSAs we use the annual precipitation in inches and a heating- and cooling- degree-days measure, which reflects the variability in temperatures from a defined base8. For these values we refer to Weather Base and Weather Data Depot, respectively, which compile these measures from the National Climatic Data Center. Finally, we create an ocean or Great Lakes
  • 34. dummy indicator that equals to 1 if a city is located within 70 or 40 miles distance from a shore of an ocean or one of the Great Lakes, respectively. Table 2 provides summary statistics of the MSAs’ characteristics included in our dataset. Table 3 reports the Spearman and Pearson correlation coefficients between the land share values employed in Davis and Palumbo (2007), Saiz’s supply elasticity values and the amenities values used in this study as well as their components (quality of life and trade productivity). The land share values are only available for 46 cities, which is relatively small subset of the 241 cities for which we have amenity, quality and productivity values.9 The correlations between the Land Share and Amenities values are high (80% and 83.7% for the Spearman and Pearson, respectively) and statistically significant. The correlations between the Land Share values and each of the components of the Amenities values independently, while somewhat lower, is still high and 7 NOAA satellites and information Comparative Climate Data:
  • 35. http://ols.nndc.noaa.gov/plolstore/plsql/olstore.prodspecific 8 Heating and cooling degree days are calculated using the year 2010 and 60 degree Fahrenheit as the base. 9 We use the time series average land share value for each of the 46 cities in order to calculate these correlation. The average land share value is based on the Q4:1984 to Q1:2014 time period. http://ols.nndc.noaa.gov/plolstore/plsql/olstore.prodspecific statistically significant. Recognizing the high correlation between the Land Share and Amenities values allows us to link our results to the land leverage hypothesis already established in the literature. Additionally, Table 3 illustrates that the correlation between the land share and elasticity values is very similar to the correlation between the amenities and elasticity values (Pearson correlation of -0.566 vs. -0.561, for example). Given the relevancy of the land supply elasticity to the land value literature, these similar correlation values further highlights the validity of amenity values as a proxy for land share. Methodology Measuring Housing Price Volatility:
  • 36. Two commonly used methodologies are employed in this paper in order to measure housing prices volatility across the MSAs included in our sample. The first measure for price volatility is the standard deviation of the returns associated with the HPI series for each of housing prices. Our standard deviation measure is based on the inflation adjusted returns from the HPI series and using a 1-year (4 quarters) rolling window. Our second approach for measuring housing price volatility captures the sensitivity of housing price changes in each MSA to changes in housing prices in the broad US market. This measure is similar to the Beta (β) often used in the finance literature as a measure for the systematic risk associated with individual stocks. Specifically, we regress the quarterly returns of each MSA in our sample (������,� ) using its HPI series on the quarterly returns calculated from the HPI series for the US as a whole (�����) as per equation (1): ������,� = �� + �� ������ (1) Where the �� coefficient is the volatility measure for MSA i.
  • 37. For robustness, we calculate both measures of housing price volatility for the full time period during which the HPI series of each MSA is available10 as well as for seven predefined sub periods of our sample. We pre-defined these seven sub periods based on inflation adjusted “up” and “down” markets so that the cutoffs between these periods are the peaks and troughs in the real prices of the broad US housing market. Panel A of Figure 1 displays the inflation adjusted HPI series for the US that spans the Q1 1975 to Q3 2013 time period along with the segmentations of the seven sub periods within. The sub periods of our sample are the following: 1. Q1 1975 – Q1 1979 – 1st up market 2. Q2 1979 – Q3 1982 – 1st down market 3. Q4 1982 – Q3 1989 – 2nd up market 4. Q4 1989 – Q1 1995 – 2nd down market 5. Q2 1995 – Q4 2006 – 3rd up market 6. Q1 2007 – Q2 2012 – 3rd down market 7. Q3 2012 – Q3 2013 – 4th up market
  • 38. The segmentation of the data into these sub periods allows us to measure the volatility of housing prices during “up” and “down” markets and examine whether the correlation between the MSAs’ housing price volatility and labor productivity or amenity values is symmetric during periods of general up and down housing price trends.11 Panel B of Figure 1 displays the inflation adjusted housing price trends in two selected MSAs for which we observed relatively high (Stockton, CA) and relatively low (Louisville, KY) 10 While the HPI is available for the US as a whole as well as for some MSAs from the 1st quarter of 1975, the HPI series begins at some later date for other MSAs. 11 Given that the HPI series becomes available at a different time for each MSA, it is possible that the beta we calculated for MSAs for the first sub period they enters our sample is extreme due to a short time period during which it is calculated. To attenuate the effect of this issue on our analysis we exclude the betas calculations for MSAs in the sub period in which they enter our sample, if it falls within the top or bottom 5% of our betas for that sub period.
  • 39. price volatility. The purpose of this panel is to visually highlight the variability in price volatility across our sample of MSAs. Housing Price Volatility and Amenities: A regression analysis is used in order to determine the relation between housing price volatility and total amenity values. We begin with a simple regression where the measured housing price volatility for each MSA (������) is the dependent variable (measured either in standard deviation or with beta) and quality of life (Quality) and trade- productivity (Productivity) or total amenity value (Amenity) serve as the independent variables. Because Albouy’s quality of life and trade-productivity measures are both used in order to derive the total amenity value (and therefore highly correlated), we make sure that we either include the former two measures or the later one in our regressions, but not all three simultaneously. ������� = �0 + �1����������� + �2���������������� (2.1) ������� = �0 + �3����������� (2.2)
  • 40. We next include additional MSAs characteristics in the regression in order examine the extent to which Albouy’s measures are able to explain housing price volatility above and beyond other observed characteristics. ������� = �0 + �1����������� + �2���������������� + ∑ ��,� ��,� � �=1 (3.1) ������� = �0 + �3����������� + ∑ ��,� ��,� � �=1 (3.2) where X is a vector of each MSA characteristics, which includes some or all of the following: the natural log of the population (Population), our education measure (Education), heating degree days in thousands (HDD), cooling degree days in thousands (CDD), average percentage of sunshine (Sunshine), precipitation in inches (Precipitation), our dummy variable for coast or the Great Lakes (Coastal/Lakes) and Saiz’s land supply elasticity measure (LSE). Given the possibility that different regions within the US
  • 41. include a cluster of higher or lower volatility MSAs, we introduce regions control dummy into our regressions. Specifically, we use the classification for 4 regions or 9 sub regions from the U.S. Census of Bureau. ������� = �0 + �1����������� + �2���������������� + ∑ ��,� ��,� � �=1 (4.1) ������� = �0 + �3����������� + ∑ ��,� ��,� � �=1 (4.2) where Y is a vector of dummies for either 3 regions or 8 sub regions, leaving the Northeast region or the New England sub region as the omitted variable, respectively. For robustness, we repeat the previous regression specifications for up- and down-trending housing price periods separately. This “up” and “down” market segregation allows us to determine whether the relation we observe between housing price volatility and amenities exists regardless of the general direction in which housing prices are heading or driven by a particular housing price trend. In order to capture housing price volatility during the up-
  • 42. and down-trending periods of our sample we calculate a volatility value for every MSA in our sample during each trend and use these values as the dependent variable in our regressions. To do so, we first use our beta and standard deviation methodologies to calculate a volatility value for every MSA during each of our predefined seven sub periods. We then average12 the values from periods 1, 3, 5 and 7 and 2, 4, and 6 to create an up- and down-trending volatility measure for every MSA, respectively. 12 We use both simple average and a weighted average that is based on the length of each sub period available for each MSA. The results using these two different approaches are qualitatively identical. Housing Price Performance and Amenity values: To determine the extent to which amenity values are related to housing price appreciation we investigate the raw real (inflation adjusted) rate of price appreciation as well as risk-adjusted
  • 43. appreciation rate. We employ the following regressions in order to determine whether housing appreciation is, on average, positively or negatively related to the amenity value of the MSA in which they are located: ������� = �0 + �1����������� + �2���������������� + ∑ ��,� ��,� � �=1 (5.1) ������� = �0 + �3����������� + ∑ ��,� ��,� � �=1 (5.2) where ������� is the average housing price appreciation rate in annual real terms in MSA i over the full sample period. We calculate housing price appreciation in real rather than nominal terms in order to avoid the possibility that the earlier segment of the data, during which inflation was higher compared with the later segment, would be overrepresented for non-housing related reasons. To examine the relation between MSA amenity values and the risk-adjusted price appreciation of housing, we employ two measures of risk- adjusted return. The first measure is the
  • 44. alpha estimation for each MSA from equation (1). This risk- adjusted measure is analogous to the Jensen Alpha that is commonly used as the risk-adjusted return for individual securities in the finance literature. The alpha estimations are then regressed on the amenity variables. �� = �0 + �1����������� + �2���������������� + ∑ ��,� ��,� � �=1 (6.1) �� = �0 + �3����������� + ∑ ��,� ��,� � �=1 (6.2) The second risk-adjusted price appreciation measure is the ratio between the standard deviation of housing price appreciation and housing price appreciation for each MSA in our sample. This measure resembles the Sharpe ratio that is commonly used in the finance literature. Similar to equation (6) we regress the Sharpe ratio of each MSA (���) on the amenity variables. ��� = �0 + �1����������� + �2���������������� + ∑ ��,� ��,� �
  • 45. �=1 (7.1) ��� = �0 + �3����������� + ∑ ��,� ��,� � �=1 (7.2) It is important to note that while Jensen alpha and Sharpe ratio are both valid and widely acceptable risk-adjusted return measures, they are fundamentally different. Jensen alpha captures the excess return of each MSA while taking into consideration the risk associated with each MSA relative to the overall market. On the other hand, the Sharpe ratio is an absolute measure, which isn’t calculated with respect the overall market. Hence, it is possible that the regression coefficients from equations (6) and (7) would not carry a consistent sign. Results Volatility and Amenities Table 4 reports the results from regression specifications (2) and (3). The standard deviation volatility measure is the dependent variable in columns (1) through (4) and the beta volatility measure is the dependent variable in columns (5) through (8). The positive and
  • 46. statistically significant coefficients of the Quality and Productivity variables in column (1) indicate that housing price volatility is higher in areas associated with higher quality of life or trade- productivity. Similarly, the positive statistically significant coefficient of the Amenity variable in column (2) indicates that areas with higher amenity value experience higher price volatility. Columns (3) and (4) provide additional evidence that the positive relations between volatility and the measures for Quality, Productivity and Amenity remain statistically significant even after controlling for a few directly observed area characteristics that would signal about the desirability of each location and its land supply constraints. These directly observed characteristics provide additional explanatory power to the regressions and enhance the adjusted R^2 values from about 36% to 63%. The results reported in columns (5) through (8) are qualitative similar to the results observed in columns (1) through (4). The similarity in the
  • 47. results suggests that the method of measuring housing price volatility does not play a major rule when the relation between level of volatility and the amenities is gauged. The signs of the additional directly observed characteristics also remain stable across the different specification. However, it appears that the adjusted R^2 in the regressions that employ Beta as a volatility measure is somewhat lower than the regressions that use standard deviation as a volatility measure. Panels A and B of Figure 2 visually illustrate the relationship between housing volatility measured either by standard deviation (Panel A) or Beta (Panel B) and the amenity values of the MSAs. These panels demonstrate that the relations between housing price volatility and amenity, presented in Table 4, are reliable across the majority of the observations in the sample and are not driven by a small segment of the data or a few outliers. Generally speaking, Table 4 and Figure 2 provide evidence that housing price volatility is higher in more attractive MSAs. These results are consistent with the hypothesis presented in our theoretical section. Moreover, our empirical results are in line
  • 48. with the land leverage hypothesis presented by Bostic, Longhofer and Redfrean (2007), since higher amenity values are associated with higher land share values. Table 5 reports the results from regression specifications (4.1) and (4.2), which control for geographical regions. As in Table 4, columns (1) through (4) and (5) through (8) use standard deviation and Beta, respectively, as the measure for housing price volatility. Columns (1), (2), (5) and (6) use the U.S. Census definition for the 4 major regions as region controls and columns (3), (4), (7) and (8) use the Census definition for the 9 sub regions. In all the columns reported within the table, the coefficient of Amenity or Quality and Productivity is positive and statistically significant. These results solidify our findings manifested in Table 4 and suggest that the positive relation between amenity values and housing price volatility areas is not due to specific regional area. With that said, the negative coefficient of the Midwest variable and the positive coefficient
  • 49. of the West variable (both statistically significant when standard deviation is used as a volatility measure) indicate that overall volatility is lower in the Midwest and higher in the West even once amenity values are accounted for. Panels A through D of Figure 3 illustrate the relation between Amenity and housing price volatility in each of the four US Census regions. Each panel includes a fitted value line for the region as well as a fitted line for the US as a whole. These panels show that the positive correlation between housing price volatility and amenity value exists in each of the four regions. However, it appears that the relation between amenity values and volatility is generally less pronounced in the Midwest and the West, as it is evident by the steepness of their fitted values relative to the steepness of the full sample fitted value line. While, on average, higher housing price volatility appears to take place in areas with higher amenity value and vice versa, it is possible that this positive relation between volatility and amenity is driven mostly by periods of particular market price trend. Given that high volatility during a
  • 50. general downtrend in housing prices (severe price declines) is more concerning than high volatility during a general uptrend trend in housing prices (sharp price increases) the symmetry in the relation between volatility and amenity should be explored. Table 6 show the results from specifications (2.1) and (2.2) when the dependent variable captures housing price volatility either during the “up” or “down” market periods included in our sample. A glance at the table reveals that the coefficients of the Quality and Productivity or Amenity variables are positive and statistically significant in each of the eight columns included in the table. Moreover, when the coefficients from the uptrend periods (columns (1) and (2), for example) are compared with those from the downtrend periods (columns (3) and (4), for example) their magnitude is very similar. These results suggest that positive relation between price volatility and amenity values, which was documented in the previous tables, also exhibits high level of symmetry.
  • 51. Performance and Amenities In traditional financial markets, assets that are paired with higher rate of return expectations are often accompanied by higher levels of risk. Recall from our Theory and Hypothesis Development section that we consider a case where amenity contribution increases as permanent incomes increase with economic growth. Under this likely case home price appreciation over time will be higher in areas with greater levels of amenities. On the other hand, we receive ambiguous results when we theoretically examine the relation between amenities and risk-adjusted price appreciation. Table 7 displays the results from our price performance analysis. Columns (1) and (2) report the results from specifications (5.1) and (5.2), which examine the relation between housing amenities and raw rates of real housing price appreciation. In these columns the coefficients of the Quality and Productivity or Amenity variables are all positive and statistically significant. These
  • 52. results are consistent with our theoretical prediction and imply that, when risk is not considered, housing price appreciation is higher in areas with higher amenity value and vice versa. Columns (3) though (6) report the relation between amenities and risk- adjusted price appreciation measured with Alpha (columns (3) and (4)) or with Sharpe ratio (columns (5) and (6)) as per equations (6) and (7), respectively. As with our theoretical prediction, these empirical results are also ambiguous. When Alpha is employed as the measure of risk- adjusted price appreciation, the observed relation is marginally negative with some statistical significance. However, when risk- adjusted return is measured with the Sharpe ratio the observed relation is positive and statistically significant. Figure 4 provides a graphical illustration of the relation between amenity levels and housing real returns on a raw and risk-adjusted basis. Consistent with the results reported in Table 7, the panels of Figure 4 show positive relation between real returns and amenities, negative
  • 53. relation between Alpha and amenities and positive relation between Sharpe ratio and amenities. The panels included in Figure 4 also provide evidence that these relations are relatively consistent throughout the sample and not driven by a handful of extreme observations. Quintile Analysis As an additional robustness test we examine the relation between local amenities and risk, returns and risk-adjusted return within subsamples of our dataset. Specifically, we segment the MSAs included in our dataset into quintiles based on their total amenity values. We then measure the average risk and return values within each quintile over the full time period as well as during our previously defined up and down markets. This type of analysis allows us to better determine whether monotonous trends in the relation between amenities and price performance can be observed. Table 8 reports the results of our quintile analysis. Consistent with the results we previously
  • 54. present in this paper, housing price appreciation in real terms (real returns), housing price volatility (measured by Beta or Standard Deviation) and the Sharpe ratio of housing are increasing with the level of local amenities. Also consistent with our previous results, the Alpha of housing is decreasing with the level of housing amenities. For each of these five measures the increase or decrease from the low (quintile 1) to the high quintile (quintile 5) of amenities is mostly monotonous. Moreover, the difference between our housing performance measures and amenities is statistically significant at the 1% level. Additionally, the differences between the levels of these measures when comparing quintile 1 to quintile 5 all (with the exception of Alpha during up markets) carry their expected sign and are keep their statistical significance. The monotonous change in the average values of our risk, return and risk adjusted return measures across quintiles provides evidence that the general relation we observe between amenities and housing price changes holds for subsets of the
  • 55. data regardless of the direction of the overall market. Overall, Table 8 strengthens the validity of the general results presented in this paper and showcases their robustness. Conclusion This paper utilizes previously estimated values for local amenities in order to determine the relation between the level of amenities observed in different location and housing price volatility and rate of appreciation in these locations. We document that amenity levels are positively related to housing price volatility as well as to raw rates of price appreciation. When risk is considered, however, amenities are positively related to risk-adjusted rate of appreciation when measured in absolute terms (Sharpe ratio), but negatively related to risk-adjusted price appreciation when measured in relative terms (Alpha). Overall, our empirical results are consistent with our theoretical model that predicts higher volatility and price appreciation in areas associated
  • 56. with more amenities and ambiguity with respect the risk adjusted returns. Previous research provide evidence for higher housing price volatility in selected large cities due to a land leverage effect (Nichols, Oliner and Mulhall (2013)). Our research makes an important contribution to the existing literature by applying land value proxies in order to provide a much broader empirical evidence to the elevated housing price volatility in more attractive locations. Moreover, by using a broader set of locations, we are also able to examine the extent to which housing price appreciation is related to locations’ amenity values, which to our knowledge, was never examined in much detail previously.
  • 57. References Albouy, D., 2009. What Are Cities worth? Land Rents, Local Productivity, and the Capitalization of Amenity Values, National Bureau Economic Research Working Paper No. 14981. Albouy, D., Ehrlich. G., 2012. Metropolitan Land Values and Housing Productivity. National Bureau Economic Research Working Paper No. 18110. Albouy, D., Ehrlich. G., 2013. The Distribution of Urban Land Values: Evidence from Market Transactions. Working paper. Black, S., 1999. Do Better Schools Matter? Parental Valuation of Elementary Education. Quarterly Journal of Economics 114, 577-600. Bogart, W.T., Cromwell, B.A., 2000. How Much Is a Neighborhood School Worth? Journal of Urban Economics 47, 280-305. Bostic, R.W., Longhofer, S.D., Redfearn, C.L., 2006. Assessing Land Taxation Regimes: Revenue Volatility and Land Leverage. Working paper.
  • 58. Bostic, R.W., Longhofer, S.D., Redfrean, C.L., 2007. Land Leverage: Decomposing Home Price Dynamics. Real Estate Economics 35, 183-208. Davis, M.A., Palumbo, M.G., 2007. The Price of Residential Land in Large US Cities. Journal of Urban Economics 63, 352-384. Dolde, W., Tirtiroglu D., 2002. Housing Price Volatility Changes and Their Effects. Real Estate Economics 30, 41-66. Glaeser, E.L., Gyourko, J., 2003. The Impact of Building Restrictions on Housing Affordability. FRB New York - Economic Policy Review 9, 21-39. Glaeser, E.L., Gyourko, J., Saiz A., 2008. Housing Supply and Housing Bubbles. Journal of Urban Economics 64, 198-217. Glaeser, E.L., Gyourko, J., Saks, R.E., 2005. Why Have Housing Prices Gone Up? The American Economic Review 95(5), 329-333. Grimes, A., Aitken, A., 2010. Housing Supply, Land Costs, and Price Adjustment. Real Estate Economics 38, 325-353.
  • 59. Gyourko, J., Saiz, A., Summers, A., 2008. A New Measure of The Local Regulatory Environment for Housing Markets: The Wharton residential land use regulatory index. Urban Studies 45, 693-729. Kok, N., Monkkonen, P., Quigley, J.M., 2014. Land Use Regulations and the Value of Land and Housing: An Intra-Metropolitan Analysis. Journal of Urban Economics, Forthcoming. Landry, C.E., Hindsley, P., 2011. Valuing Beach Quality with Hedonic Property Models, Land Economics 87, 92-108. Miao, H., Ramchander, S., Simpson, M.W., 2011. Return and Volatility Transmission in U.S. Housing Markets. Real Estate Economics 39, 701-741. Moretti, E., 2004. Estimating the Social Return to Higher Education: Evidence from Longitudinal and Repeated Cross-Sectional Data. Journal of Econometrics121, 175-212. Nichols, J.B., Oliner, S.D., Mulhall, M.R., 2013. Swings in Commercial and Residential Land Prices in the United States. Journal of Urban Economics 73, 57-
  • 60. 76. Paciorek, A., 2013. Supply Constraints and Housing Market Dynamics. Journal of Urban Economics 77, 11-26 Rosen, S., 1974. Hedonic Prices and Implicit Markets: Product Differentiation in Pure Competition. Journal of Political Economy 82, 34-55. Rosenthal, S.S., Strange, W.C., 2008. The Attenuation of Human Capital Spillovers, Journal of Urban Economics 64, 373-389. Saiz, A., 2010. The Geographic Determinants of Housing Supply. The Quarterly Journal of Economics 125, 1253-1296. Turnbull, G. K., Zahirovic-Herbert V., Mothorpe, C., 2013. Flooding and Liquidity on the Bayou: The Capitalization of Flood Risk into House Value and Ease-of- Sale, Real Estate Economics 41, 103-129. Sirmans, C.F., Slade, B.A., 2012. National Transaction-Based Land Price Indices. The Journal of Real Estate Finance and Economics 45, 829-845. Wyman, D., Hutchinson N., Tiwari, P., 2014. Testing the
  • 61. Waters: A Spatial Econometric Pricing Model of Different Waterfront Views, Journal of Real Estate Research 36, 363-382. Zhou, Y., Haurin, D.R., 2010. On the Determinants of House Volatility. Journal of Real Estate Research 32, 377-395. Figure 1. House Prices and Volatility Panel A: US Inflation-Adjusted Housing Price Index Q1 1975 – Q3 2013
  • 62. Note: dotted lines indicate divisions between the up and down markets in this study Panel B: Inflation-Adjusted Housing Price Index in Selected MSAs 90 115 140 165 1 9 7 5 1 9 7 7 1 9 7 9 1 9
  • 71. 1 2 0 0 2 = 1 0 0 Louisville, KY Stockton, CA Figure 2. Volatility and amenity values Figure 3: Housing volatilities vs. amenities (by region) 0 .0 5
  • 72. .1 .1 5 -.2 -.1 0 .1 .2 .3 US East East Region 0 .0 5 .1 .1 5 -.2 -.1 0 .1 .2 .3 US Midwest Midwest Region 0 .0 5 .1 .1
  • 73. 5 -.2 -.1 0 .1 .2 .3 US South South Region 0 .0 5 .1 .1 5 -.2 -.1 0 .1 .2 .3 US West West Region S ta n d a rd D e v
  • 74. ia ti o n Amenity Figure 4. Housing returns vs. amenities -. 0 5 0 .0 5 -.2 -.1 0 .1 .2 .3 Amenity Panel A. Real Returns -. 0 2 0
  • 75. .0 2 -.2 -.1 0 .1 .2 .3 Amenity Panel B. Alpha (systematic risk adjusted returns) -. 5 0 .5 -.2 -.1 0 .1 .2 .3 Amenity Panel C. Sharpe Ratio (total risk adjusted returns) Table 1. Quality of life, trade-productivity and amenity values for selected MSAs Total Amenities Quality of Life Trade Productivity Metropolitan area Value Rank Value Rank Value Rank
  • 76. Total Amenities: Top 5 metro areas San Francisco-Oakland-San Jose, CA 0.323 1 0.138 3 0.289 1 Santa Barbara-Santa Maria-Lompoc, CA 0.255 2 0.176 2 0.125 7 Honolulu, HI 0.24 3 0.204 1 0.057 22 Salinas (Monterey-Carmel), CA 0.229 4 0.137 4 0.144 4 San Diego, CA 0.185 5 0.123 7 0.098 11 Total Amenities : Bottom 5 metro areas Joplin, MO -0.168 261 -0.011 118 -0.246 272 Fort Smith, AR-OK -0.169 262 -0.045 206 -0.194 255 Johnstown, PA -0.191 272 -0.062 250 -0.201 258 Brownsville-Harlingen-San Benito, TX -0.198 274 -0.057 238 -0.221 267 McAllen-Edinburg-Mission, TX -0.225 276 -0.079 272 -0.228 270 Quality of Life: Top 5 metro areas Honolulu, HI 0.24 3 0.204 1 0.057 22 Santa Barbara-Santa Maria-Lompoc, CA 0.255 2 0.176 2 0.125
  • 77. 7 San Francisco-Oakland-San Jose, CA 0.323 1 0.138 3 0.289 1 Salinas (Monterey-Carmel), CA 0.229 4 0.137 4 0.144 4 Santa Fe, NM 0.116 12 0.127 5 -0.017 60 Quality of Life: Bottom 5 metro areas Saginaw-Bay City-Midland, MI -0.096 168 -0.074 270 -0.035 75 McAllen-Edinburg-Mission, TX -0.225 276 -0.079 272 -0.228 270 Decatur, IL -0.14 232 -0.089 274 -0.08 118 Beaumont-Port Arthur, TX -0.153 253 -0.108 275 -0.07 107 Kokomo, IN -0.091 158 -0.11 276 0.029 33 Trade Productivity: Top 5 metro areas San Francisco-Oakland-San Jose, CA 0.323 1 0.138 3 0.289 1 New York, N.New Jersey, Long Island 0.163 8 0.029 51 0.209 2 Los Angeles-Riverside-Orange Co., CA 0.177 6 0.081 14 0.15 3 Salinas (Monterey-Carmel), CA 0.229 4 0.137 4 0.144 4
  • 78. Chicago-Gary-Kenosha, IL-IN-WI 0.089 15 0.005 80 0.131 5 Trade Productivity: Bottom 5 metro areas Brownsville-Harlingen-San Benito, TX -0.198 274 -0.057 238 -0.221 267 Abilene, TX -0.139 231 0.004 83 -0.223 268 Wichita Falls, TX -0.152 251 -0.008 102 -0.226 269 McAllen-Edinburg-Mission, TX -0.225 276 -0.079 272 -0.228 270 Joplin, MO -0.168 261 -0.011 118 -0.246 272 Note: This table illustrates the variation in amenity values across MSAs, and is a sub-set of the data from Table A1 of Albouy (2009). Table 2. Summary statistics Variables Mean STD Min Max Obs. House price returns Total return: over sample period1 1.11 .365 .628 3.72 238 Total return: annual average .024 .006 .014 .042 238
  • 79. Real return: annual average .003 .008 -.013 .036 238 House price volatility Standard deviation (annual) .052 .025 .016 .131 238 Beta (quarter) .846 .525 .099 2.71 238 Albouy measures Quality (quality of life) -.007 .049 -.117 .178 238 Productivity (trade productivity) -.064 .084 -.246 .285 238 Amenity (total amenities) -.048 .082 -.229 .315 238 Heating Days (heating degree days) 3,160 1,727 0 8,194 237 Cooling Days (cooling degree days) 2,690 1,341 10 6,487 237 Precipitation (annual rainfall, inches) 37 14 3 66 238 Coast (coastal/great lakes, 1/0) .328 .471 0 1 238 Census measures (year 2000) Population 928,577 2,080,520 101,541 21,000,000 238 Education (% bachelor degree 25+) .279 .098 .053 .642 238 Income (median household income) 48,736 7,657 31,264 85,660 238
  • 80. Saiz (2010) measure Elasticity (land supply elasticity) 2 2.57 1.36 .62 7.94 208 Davis and Palumbo (2007) measure Land Share (%, land value/total value) .358 .180 .093 .821 40 Note: 1) The sample is an unbalanced panel dataset. Sample time frame has an average of 125 quarters (72 min, 153 max) per MSA from 1975 to 2013. 2) Although Saiz (2010) covers 95 MSAs/NECMAs, we infer elasticities for smaller geographic areas in our sample that comprise those metropolitan areas based on a weighted average of population. Table 3. Correlation matrix Land Share Amenities Quality Productivity Elasticity Land Share 1 .800*** .764*** .567*** -.598***
  • 81. Amenities .837*** 1 .692*** .856*** -.619*** Quality .815*** .771*** 1 .288* -.699*** Productivity .635*** .815*** .261*** 1 -.302** Elasticity -.566*** -.561*** -.414*** -.482*** 1 Notes: The upper diagonal reports Spearman correlation coefficients. The bottom diagonal reports Pearson correlation coefficients. The symbols ***,**,* indicate statistical significance at the 1%, 5%, and 10% level, respectively. Table 4. Regression analysis: volatility, amenities and area characteristics (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) Variables Standard Deviation (total volatility) Beta (systematic volatility) Quality 0.226*** 0.101*** 4.131*** 2.073*** [8.34] [2.89] [6.82] [2.43] Productivity 0.094*** 0.042 1.966*** 1.692***
  • 82. [5.97] [1.57] [5.59] [2.63] Amenity 0.183*** 0.088*** 3.564*** 2.307*** [11.67] [2.93] [10.18] [3.16] Population -0.004** -0.005** -0.097*** -0.088*** [-2.83] [-3.76] [-2.65] [-2.79] Education -0.054*** -0.051*** -1.019*** -1.076*** [-4.10] [-4.08] [-3.15] [-3.54] Heating Days -0.000*** -0.000*** -0.000*** -0.000*** [-4.73] [-4.74] [-2.98] [-2.96] Cooling Days -0.000 -0.000 0.000 0.000 [0.21] [-0.12] [0.45] [0.42] Precipitation -0.000*** -0.000*** -0.007*** -0.007*** [-4.61] [-4.66] [-3.18] [-3.16] Coastal/Lakes 0.005* 0.005* .083 0.082 [1.85] [1.84] [1.22] [1.21] ln(Income) .044*** 0.041*** 0.463 0.506 [3.19] [3.09] [1.37] [1.56] Elasticity -0.004*** -0.004*** -.103*** -0.101***
  • 83. [-3.87] [-4.02] [-3.98] [-3.95] Constant 0.059*** 0.060*** -0.304** 0.263* 1.002*** 1.018*** -1.690*** -2.281*** [36.92] [40.61] [2.07] [-1.91] [27.95] [30.76] [-0.47] [-0.68] Obs. 238 238 207 207 238 238 207 207 Adj. R^2 0.3699 0.3634 0.632 0.633 0.303 0.302 0.526 0.529 Notes: The symbols ***,**,* indicate statistical significance at the 1%, 5%, and 10% level, respectively. The observations decrease in Models (3, 4, 7 and 8) due to missing data for some of the independent variables. Table 5. Regression analysis: volatility and amenities (with regional controls) (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) Variables Standard Deviation (total volatility) Beta (systematic volatility) Quality 0.126*** 0.0836*** 2.451*** 1.338** [4.52] [2.98] [3.72] [2.05] Productivity 0.085*** 0.0697*** 1.836*** 1.505*** [5.55] [4.50] [5.05] [4.18]
  • 84. Amenity 0.130*** 0.098*** 2.689*** 1.913*** [7.98] [5.86] [6.95] [4.91] Midwest -0.013*** -0.014*** -0.119 -0.119 [-3.40] [-3.41] [-1.23] [-1.24] South 0.000 0.000 0.080 0.070 [0.06] [0.02] [0.85] [0.77] West 0.018*** 0.017*** 0.378*** 0.366*** [3.79] [3.86] [3.44] [3.44] MA -0.024*** -0.024*** -0.341* -0.332* [-2.96] [-2.94] [-1.83] [-1.78] ENC -0.033*** -0.033*** -0.396** -0.381** [-4.38] [-4.34] [-2.24] [-2.16] WNC -0.032*** -0.034*** -0.425 -0.437 [-4.14] [-4.19] [-2.28] [-2.35] SA -0.013* -0.013* 0.042 0.016 [-1.67] [-1.78] [0.24] [0.09] ESC -0.031*** -0.032*** -0.366* -0.371* [-3.71] [-3.73] [-1.92] [-1.94]
  • 85. WSC -0.022*** -0.023*** -0.474** -0.490*** [-2.83] [-2.89] [-2.59] [-2.69] MTN -0.007 -0.007 0.073 0.040 [-0.80] [-0.91] [0.39] [0.22] P 0.084 0.0076 0.4252 0.4203 [1.05] [1.01] [1.55] [1.47] Constant 0.0584*** 0.0585*** 0.0758*** 0.0757*** 0.8830*** 0.8819*** 1.0596*** 1.0580*** [16.64] [16.72] [11.2289] [11.2300] [9.8210] [9.8379] [6.0716] [6.0759] Obs. 238 238 238 238 238 238 238 238 Adj R^2 0.497 0.499 0.547 0.548 0.369 0.372 0.456 0.455 Note: The symbols ***,**,* indicate statistical significance at the 1%, 5%, and 10% level, respectively Table 6. Regression analysis: volatility (by up and down market segmentation) (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) Up Markets Down Markets Up Markets Down Markets Variables Volatility (Standard Deviation) Volatility (Beta)
  • 86. Quality 0.186*** 0.187*** 4.980 *** 3.731*** [7.56] [7.12] [5.88] [5.75] Productivity 0.057*** 0.057*** 0.882* 1.234*** [3.96] [3.76] [1.79] [3.27] Amenity 0.134*** 0.134*** 3.050*** 2.764*** [9.30] [8.79] [6.15] [7.32] Constant 0.049*** 0.051*** 0.051*** 0.053*** 1.031*** 1.09*** 1.06*** 1.09*** [33.84] [37.33] [33.39] [36.83] [20.68] [23.26] [27.53] [30.44] Obs. 238 238 238 238 238 238 238 238 Adj. R^2 0.282 0.265 0.259 0.243 0.158 0.134 0.190 0.182 Notes: The symbols ***,**,* indicate statistical significance at the 1%, 5%, and 10% level, respectively. Models (1, 2, 5, and 6) utilize observations from “up markets” (appreciating), while the other models utilize observations from down markets (depreciating).
  • 87. Table 7. Regression analysis: returns and risk-adjusted returns (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) Variables Real Returns (annual) Alpha (quarterly) Sharpe Ratio (annual) Quality 0.078*** 0.006 1.191*** [8.14] [0.98] [5.30] Productivity 0.011*** -0.009** -0.085 [2.16] [-2.43] [-0.69] Amenity 0.044*** -0.005 0.445*** [7.42] [-1.26] [3.21] Regional Fixed Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Effects Constant 0.017*** 0.018*** 0.001 0.001 0.219*** 0.224*** [7.39] [7.19] [0.71] [0.74] [4.00] [3.94] Obs. 238 238 238 238 238 238
  • 88. Adj. R^2 0.521 0.482 0.249 0.237 0.293 0.243 Note: The symbols ***,**,* indicate statistical significance at the 1%, 5%, and 10% level, respectively. Table 8. Quintile analysis: risk, returns, and risk-adjusted returns Real returns (annual) All markets 0.33% *** 0.08% 0.01% -0.01% 0.38% *** 1.24% *** 1.16% *** Up markets 2.02% *** 0.91% *** 0.94% *** 1.59% *** 2.50% *** 4.30% *** 3.39% *** Down markets -2.21% *** -1.14% *** -1.44% *** -2.33% *** - 2.87% *** -3.36% *** -2.22% *** Alpha (annualized) All markets 0.29% ** 1.16% *** 0.82% *** 0.18% -0.18% - 0.59% * -1.75% *** Up markets -0.67% *** 0.11% 0.02% -1.27% ** -1.53% ** - 0.69% -0.80%
  • 89. Down markets 0.91% *** 2.03% *** 1.74% *** 0.83% *** 0.39% -0.57% -2.61% *** Sharpe ratio (real return per unit of standard deviation, annual) All markets 0.052 *** 0.033 0.002 0.002 0.068 *** 0.162 *** 0.129 *** Up markets 0.432 *** 0.313 *** 0.274 *** 0.386 *** 0.528 *** 0.672 *** 0.359 *** Down markets -0.470 *** -0.318 *** -0.379 *** -0.484 *** - 0.606 *** -0.571 *** -0.253 *** Volatility (standard deviation, annual) All markets 5.16% *** 3.61% *** 3.97% *** 4.80% *** 5.86% *** 7.74% *** 4.13% *** Up markets 4.44% *** 3.31% *** 3.65% *** 4.09% *** 4.89% *** 6.37% *** 3.05% ** Down markets 4.68% *** 3.48% *** 3.70% *** 4.50% *** 5.14% *** 6.72% *** 3.24% *** Volatility (Beta, quarterly) All markets 0.846 *** 0.501 *** 0.606 *** 0.825 *** 1.014 *** 1.317 *** 0.817 *** Up markets 0.944 *** 0.603 *** 0.647 *** 0.989 *** 1.180 *** 1.333 *** 0.729 *** Down markets 0.953 *** 0.663 *** 0.820 *** 0.903 *** 1.076 *** 1.327 *** 0.664 ***
  • 90. AmenityAmenity Amenity Amenity Amenity Amenity Quintiles Sample (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (5-1) Full Quintile Quintile Quintile Quintile Quintile Notes: Quintiles based on Amenity (1 = low amenities, 5 = high amenities). The symbols ***,**,* indicate statistical significance at the 1%, 5%, and 10% level, respectively. Problem 1YearQQuartely return - CRE_Atlanta_GAQuarterly return - CRE_Denver_COQuarterly return - CRE_USAInflation index19774100.00197813.24%2.58%2.90%102.09a. Correlation between Altalnta and Denver for the 1990:1-2014:2 time period21.76%2.25%3.07%104.9931.54%8.50%3.39%107.0943.9 8%9.50%5.89%109.02b. Correlation between Denver and the USA for the 1978:1- 2014:2 time period197912.75%4.09%3.81%112.4023.33%1.82%4.32%116.4 332.76%2.23%4.75%120.13c. Correlation between USA and inflation rate for the 1995:1 - 2014:2 time period48.68%6.97%6.19%123.51198012.15%5.00%5.54%128.9 923.27%2.77%2.36%133.17d. The annual standard deviation of returns for the USA for the 1990:1-2014:2 time period32.17%2.21%3.79%135.2746.82%9.43%5.32%138.97198 112.21%6.71%2.96%142.51e. The 3-year standard deviation of
  • 91. returns for the USA for the 1990:1-2014:2 time period23.13%2.63%4.23%145.8930.63%0.59%3.21%150.0845.6 1%27.87%5.29%151.37f. The geometric average USA annual returns for the 1990:1-2014:2 time period198212.43%1.73%2.49%152.1723.30%0.40%2.07%156.2 032.48%2.69%1.52%157.6542.97%0.91%3.04%157.17198311.7 4%1.89%1.75%157.6523.25%1.47%2.54%160.2334.52%2.06%2 .96%162.1644.30%4.10%5.31%163.12198412.99%2.24%3.35% 165.2224.14%3.78%3.16%166.9932.56%0.45%2.46%169.0843. 48%0.99%4.21%169.57198514.30%- 0.95%2.08%171.3423.53%1.89%2.60%173.2731.58%1.31%2.39 %174.4044.11%4.31%3.73%176.01198612.90%0.46%2.03%175 .2022.49%1.49%1.96%176.3332.82%- 1.50%1.50%177.4640.97%- 1.94%2.57%177.94198711.35%1.28%1.83%180.5220.71%- 1.81%1.19%182.7730.27%0.24%2.09%185.1940.74%- 1.11%2.67%185.83198811.22%0.63%1.84%187.6021.39%- 0.43%2.00%190.0230.30%0.68%2.39%192.9141.39%2.11%3.07 %194.04198912.29%0.56%1.75%196.942- 0.24%0.78%2.00%199.8430.55%1.68%2.05%201.2940.76%- 3.46%1.75%203.06199011.90%0.34%1.38%207.2520.25%1.28 %1.52%209.183-2.18%-0.10%0.84%213.694-1.87%-3.34%- 1.43%215.4619911-2.23%-2.10%0.05%217.3920.70%- 0.51%0.01%219.003-1.05%-0.31%-0.33%220.934-6.05%- 4.34%-5.33%222.06199210.41%-0.83%-0.03%224.322- 0.79%0.34%-1.03%225.7630.20%-1.24%-0.44%227.5440.13%- 1.65%-2.81%228.50199311.84%1.79%0.77%231.2422.34%- 8.31%-0.24%232.5332.06%1.84%1.10%233.6642.84%1.66%- 0.25%234.78199411.98%1.98%1.31%237.0423.74%3.35%1.54 %238.3333.69%2.77%1.51%240.5844.15%4.96%1.88%241.061 99513.39%2.43%2.11%243.8023.31%2.06%2.08%245.5732.85 %2.53%2.06%246.7043.09%- 1.15%1.09%247.18199612.57%2.33%2.40%250.7223.04%3.06 %2.29%252.3332.39%2.48%2.63%254.1144.58%2.74%2.61%25 5.39199712.46%2.80%2.34%257.6522.72%2.68%2.82%258.133 3.65%2.75%3.38%259.5845.35%3.63%4.71%259.74199812.36
  • 92. %5.43%4.14%261.1923.73%6.67%4.19%262.4833.06%3.30%3. 46%263.4542.55%3.15%3.55%263.93199912.58%3.03%2.59%2 65.7022.05%3.12%2.62%267.6332.64%3.71%2.81%270.3742.3 7%2.55%2.89%271.01200012.12%4.09%2.40%275.6822.39%3. 78%3.05%277.6231.99%1.84%2.94%279.7142.35%2.72%3.33% 280.19200112.24%2.05%2.36%283.7422.00%1.84%2.47%286.6 331.53%0.75%1.60%287.1240.02%0.32%0.67%284.54200211.3 6%2.34%1.51%287.9221.18%1.10%1.61%289.6931.02%- 0.07%1.79%291.4740.30%0.35%1.67%291.30200310.81%1.12 %1.88%296.6221.39%0.93%2.09%295.8130.87%2.64%1.97%29 8.2341.61%1.16%2.76%296.78200412.27%1.13%2.56%301.772 2.00%1.39%3.13%305.4832.73%3.61%3.42%305.8043.78%2.07 %4.66%306.44200512.47%4.47%3.51%311.2724.05%4.24%5.3 4%313.2034.10%4.78%4.44%320.1344.76%3.85%5.43%316.91 200613.07%3.00%3.62%321.7424.06%4.06%4.01%326.7333.54 %3.10%3.51%326.7343.10%3.85%4.51%324.96200712.59%3.3 3%3.62%330.6823.18%5.01%4.59%335.5131.95%2.63%3.56%3 35.7341.82%3.47%3.21%338.22200811.63%1.20%1.60%343.85 20.36%1.80%0.56%352.363-0.37%0.22%-0.17%352.314-7.03%- 6.04%-8.29%338.5320091-7.43%-7.60%-7.33%342.532-5.30%- 4.56%-5.20%347.333-3.05%-2.75%-3.32%347.784-2.81%- 1.68%- 2.11%347.74201010.95%1.04%0.76%350.4522.29%3.69%3.31 %350.9933.24%4.18%3.86%351.7542.76%6.35%4.62%352.952 01112.79%3.59%3.36%359.8523.20%3.67%3.94%363.4832.80 %3.48%3.30%365.3643.01%3.85%2.96%363.40201212.26%2.8 7%2.59%369.3923.25%3.68%2.68%369.5332.14%2.88%2.34%3 72.6441.97%3.49%2.54%369.73201312.28%2.76%2.57%374.84 22.40%3.85%2.87%376.0132.68%3.35%2.59%377.0543.22%4.2 2%2.53%375.28201412.47%2.97%2.74%380.5023.57%3.44%2. 91%383.81 Problem 2DateKBH priceHME priceSPY price4/1/1515.4468.48210.63Beta KBH:3/2/1515.6269.29206.42999Beta HME:2/2/1513.9566.77209.72385Which company has a higher Beta?1/2/1512.4348469.71426198.56366In one to two sentences
  • 93. explain why you did or didn’t expect that company to be associated with a higher Beta.12/1/1416.5165864.86887204.6265911/3/1417.5345264.46 344205.1469710/1/1415.6836562.8725199.661879/2/1414.8865 256.93818195.067848/1/1417.6864662.78452197.796717/1/141 6.2169263.58646190.287296/2/1418.5847961.81775192.879145 /1/1416.39660.09737188.977714/1/1416.4258558.84649184.691 683/3/1416.8774357.43264183.416662/3/1420.2648456.305391 81.907641/2/1419.1863252.60588173.9884212/2/1318.1347450. 59601180.3452811/1/1317.390749.61466175.7877210/1/1316.8 102156.2014170.727749/3/1317.8503353.8158163.171788/1/13 15.8790753.7692158.16647/1/1317.5828758.78954163.056856/ 3/1319.4163960.22681155.044635/1/1321.9188555.98872157.1 4164/1/1322.2947258.75099153.517113/1/1321.5095157.80311 50.623282/1/1318.4663656.89166145.113161/2/1318.8164555.3 8373143.28512/3/1215.5899355.23957136.307411/1/1214.1690 753.05918135.1003410/1/1215.7675354.16706134.340039/4/12 14.1372754.59477136.830098/1/1210.8763456.89368133.44717 /2/129.1030357.85545130.185616/1/129.6293254.10776128.663 575/1/127.1237352.85559123.645884/2/128.5042653.27468131. 545973/1/128.719853.23978132.430042/1/1211.1887850.29026 128.303311/3/128.7796851.42603122.9659312/1/116.5409649.6 9111117.5161711/1/117.1541747.44695116.3010210/3/116.722 9850.29536116.775579/1/115.6523248.46799105.284118/1/116. 3564457.10103113.138247/1/118.128255.39695119.719926/1/1 19.3632251.47384122.163765/2/1111.7566852.33625124.25999 4/1/1111.2454153.05796125.669323/1/1111.8452949.33386122. 132192/1/1112.6165749.30875122.117521/3/1114.0705746.084 4118.0178912/1/1012.7905745.92714115.3306711/1/1010.7141 144.35458108.1036910/1/109.9048844.60028108.103699/1/101 0.6776743.33066104.125878/2/109.716441.3648195.567367/1/1 010.6678740.20872100.06856/1/1010.3116536.4849493.670725 /3/1013.5738839.3668398.781794/1/1017.3130939.76447107.30 7893/1/1015.6499837.45175105.673122/1/1015.2108536.65159 9.608961/4/1014.217735.0283296.5956912/1/0912.7289437.699 1100.238611/2/0912.6079735.5024298.3598410/1/0913.136013
  • 94. 0.4530292.651859/1/0915.387133.492194.468038/3/0916.86932 9.5125491.233167/1/0915.4046827.2841987.98316/1/0912.6264 826.0613781.874775/1/0913.8448225.4499681.928434/1/0916.6 245127.3107777.40393/2/0912.1256822.9713270.409032/2/098. 1880619.8909964.994311/2/099.761126.2200272.818612/1/081 2.4598129.6609879.3329711/3/0810.6393328.4920878.5633410 /1/0815.1980929.0368984.440999/2/0817.9208241.55811101.14 9548/1/0818.940737.82899111.665477/1/0816.0176438.994671 09.966096/2/0815.1709934.06187110.963195/1/0818.3790336.2 873121.082784/1/0819.9612236.76734119.279683/3/0821.9395 933.5641113.853182/1/0821.2298632.18629114.880471/2/0824. 166132.93156117.9280312/3/0718.9813730.92505125.5169111/ 1/0718.3574431.15949126.9464310/1/0724.0472934.94926132. 061519/4/0721.8026535.46582130.293858/1/0726.3963534.541 45125.437647/2/0727.4588531.08261123.848316/1/0733.98476 34.8622127.851365/1/0739.6129238.66865129.748384/2/0737.8 615236.95248125.49173/1/0736.625535.0352120.168732/1/074 2.5137438.81669118.792061/3/0746.3282942.21426121.169091 2/1/0643.816238.91801119.3736811/1/0644.1665240.58583117. 7985710/2/0638.178541.03386115.501779/1/0637.2100337.129 9111.972768/1/0636.326536.94802109.028827/3/0635.9295735. 82217106.700356/1/0638.7434335.64878106.224655/1/0643.26 4231.94326105.94834/3/0651.8118731.71124109.238683/1/065 4.6814232.39593107.8762/1/0656.4065231.29282106.124531/3/ 0663.8954428.69802105.5203812/1/0560.9270725.52603103.04 58211/1/0558.5037326.04531103.2433710/3/0554.6423123.919 9498.896639/1/0561.2060824.16622101.292278/1/0562.042232 5.24985100.485847/1/0568.3112227.75781101.436766/1/0563.5 742226.0843497.698675/2/0556.3269424.9808297.550884/25/0 547.3860924.9976394.50548