SlideShare a Scribd company logo
1 of 92
QI PLAN PART 2 2
QI PLAN PART 2 5
Running head: QI PLAN PART 2 1
QI Plan Part 2
This methodology is chosen because in performance
improvement it entails satisfactory of the patients, the process
of delivery and improvement of the processes. The quality
improvement (QI) is identified to focus on bringing out the gap
in between the current levels of quality and the expected quality
levels. The Quality Improvement uses the tools for managing
quality together with the principles towards understanding and
address systems deficiencies hence improving or re-designing
efficiently the effective healthcare processes (Scales, 2014).
Moreover, setting up a Quality Improvement process is termed
to be an easy task but in order to integrate these processes in
day to day activities, there have to be effective implementation
via the leadership dedication, empowering of the employees, the
healthy culture of business and the effectiveness of strategic
planning that management has been embraced along with the
desired performances.
The information technology applications include the Hospital
Admission Risk Prediction (HARP) and the Episheet. In terms
of improving the performance area, the HARP aims in
predicting the future events, creating the intervention
mechanism to the health care providers and generating the
information regarding patient risk within future framework
(Scales, 2014). The other application tool named Episheet is a
qualitative tool which is applied in epidemiologic data analysis.
It will help improve the performance area through gathering of
the information and ensuring the priority of the healthcare
organization.
In order to meet the performance improvement plan, innovation
technology has to be considered in all applications. The IT
applications are applied in an object oriented technology as well
as in a computerized patient records systems and might also be
used in the specific components of IT. Certainly, the object
oriented technology would ensure that all different systems
within the organization are connected and proper management
(Hermann, 2005). The information technology entails the
management of the patient’s records through computerization in
order to prevent loss or from being accessed by the illegitimate
persons. Furthermore, this aspect explores that for the use of the
specific IT components, it is quite easy to monitor an
organizational quality performance because the organization
does not need change from the component directly to the other
when delivering its services.
The quality indicators are identified as the guide to evaluation
of the appropriate performance of an organization. The reason is
that the performance is always evaluated continuously and at
last at the end of the projects in a way that the organization
carries out the process. Therefore, the benchmarks are termed as
the programs as well as the operations which are set in order to
make assessment of organizational performances. It is ideally
achieved through some of the standards and run trial tests
(Scales, 2014). In quality improvement, this enables in
determining how effectively procedures which are being
adhered to by an organization are analyzed. It is therefore
through these aspects that the performance of the information
technology within the organization is identified to have been
reviewed. On the other side, milestones mark the end of the
project, an end of a certain stage or particular step. Moreover,
the performance is progressively monitored, improved and
improved after milestones.
It is aligned with the performance mission, vision and the
strategic plan in a way that healthcare’s provision targets goal
by ensuring that each patient receives the quality health care
services. The mission, vision and the strategic plan is to
provide the appropriate satisfactory services to patients and
work towards diverse population. The performance
improvement is aligned with the plans of the health care
organization through quality improvement and the patient’s
satisfactory which have to be achieved. These tools have
similarity like; they are used in evaluating the effectiveness of
the health care services in healthcare organization settings.
They attributed to the quality of services provided by the
healthcare organization through directing the organization
towards improvement on their services. Child Health Care
Quality measurement is known to be much more concerned with
children health quality. Meaning that, it contains information
and also tools that can be used to evaluate the healthcare quality
for children. It is based in the healthcare organization and the
information that is evaluated is signifies health care
organization (Hermann, 2005). The ambulatory care is used
provision as well as evaluation of the health care organization
readiness. It presents the tests regarding health quality
preparedness along introducing a task. Contrary to the child
healthcare Quality toolbox, the ambulatory care tool obtains
information from people around.
References
Gao, Q. (2014). A Procedural Framework for Trans boundary
Water Management in the Mekong River Basin Shared Mekong
for a Common Future.
Hermann, R. (2005). Improving Mental Healthcare: A Guide to
Measurement-Based Quality Improvement. Arlington: American
Psychiatric Pub.
Scales, D. C., & Rubenfeld, G. D. (2014). The organization of
critical care: An evidence-based approach to improving quality.
What is written on the file you have attached is not what I
expected , there are some issues:
1- you did not mention the reference that I gave you, that should
be mentioned and all the essay must be based on (MRW).
2- No equations on the essay except one basic equation about
education. You can find on the reference there are many
equations are related to the subject.
3- You have to focus on the data between p.436-436 analyze
them with interpretation and explanation.
4- No problem if you use other references related to the main
reference. You can use quotations and citations as well.
In the equation you can use a special format for that on
(Microsoft Word) the way that you wrote the equations the last
time is not acceptable.
I need the code file as wellalso; you have to use Harvard style
with the references
Regards
Kindly do not forget to put:
- Brief introduction about the subject
- Brief conclusion
- Equations
- Graphs if you could
- Citations
- Quotations with page numbers after the date
- List of references in the last page of the essay
- 1500 words is the maximum number do not make it more
Professional work are needed I'm a postgraduate student
Please answer the question carefully this time I paid a lot of
money for a good work and that was not.
PLEASE SEE NEXT PAGE
Introduction:
The physical to human capital proportion is composed in
expanding work Solow sort demonstrate as opposed to level of
them. It is accepted that the development of yield relies on upon
the physical to human capital proportion where human capital is
most certainly not just measured by instruction additionally by
wellbeing or sustenance status. Accordingly, human capital is
characterized in this study with individual instruction level and
dietary status. In the event that there is an irregularity impact in
the middle of physical and human capital, the awkwardness
impact that is a symmetric condition on the physical to human
capital proportion will be fundamentally beneath or over its
enduring state esteem. The uneven unevenness impact is
exhibited by a kilter U-molded reliance or if the every capita
yield development depends just as decidedly or just as adversely
on the physical to human degree. They generally state prove
that development depends absolutely on the physical to human
capital degree. Islam (1995) discovers negative human capital
coefficients. This negative sign of human capital coefficients is
considered by us to be an evidence for the importance of
physical to human capital degree in development study. They
draw thoughtfulness regarding the complementarities between
human capital and physical capital. The complementarities
between human capital and physical capital are the regular of
the generation technique since gear needs qualified laborers to
oversee them and qualified mechanics to settle them. Also, even
advanced agrarian creation obliges a generally educated
horticulture workforce where specialists who can understand
directions on a compost pack, get it data contained in manual
conveyed by augmentation specialists and get it the substance of
a repair manual for agrarian supplies and up-to-the-moment
administrations need individuals who can make basic
estimations quickly and exactly. On the off chance that nations
concentrate on physical capital while overlooking their human
capital, they will before long get to be cognizant that the comes
back to physical capital are more terrible than they need to be
then they will have poorer yield. They likewise uncovered that
presenting unrivaled strategies for creation, better approaches
for doing things and presenting more compound and entangled
items are simpler said than done on the off chance that
purchasers, laborers and buyers have unacceptable preparing
and instruction to empower them to comprehend the new
engineering.
Data:
We have utilized information for 1990 and 2000 for 36
nations where 1980' every capita GDP level information is
gotten for beginning starting salary level. The physical cash
flow to education*worker exertion level information is
computed as electric power utilization (kwh) to Education (E)
information times the specialist exertion record (e) (EL/E*e).
EL/E*e electric force utilization (kwh) demonstrated as (EL)
stands for physical capital intermediary and Education (E)
information is the aggregate instructed individuals who took
normal Years of School from instructive accomplishment of the
matured 15. Every capita dietary vitality supply (DES) is taken
from Fao1 to compute the specialist exertion level (e).
Downright populace variables are taken from the World
Improvement Indicators to figure populace development rates.
Gross domestic product every capita and all out populaces and
EL/E*e electric force utilization (kwh) are from World Bank's
World Development Indicators2. Instruction (E) information
originates from the Barro- Lee information set. Change in
physical cashflow to instruction information is figured as
change in EL/E*e electric force utilization (kwh) to Education
(E) information and the laborer exertion record (e) (EL/E*e).
Since we plan to utilize physical to human capital degree
as the integral communication in our increasing Solow model,
we ought to draw the illustrations of the normal every capita
salary development and the EL/E*e. The reliance on the every
capita salary development on K/H proportion in figure 1 is not
U molded. One-part endogenous development models expect a
U-formed reliance of generation development on the backwards
proportion of physical to human capital. Greenwood (1997) says
that financial development hypothesis equivocally infers the
lopsidedness impact. This awkwardness impact is portrayed as
the proportion of physical to human capital or human to
physical capital. As we see from the figure 1, aggregate and
sub-examples demonstrates no U-formed. In any case, it is
tricky to close there is a positive relationship between normal
every capita pay development and EL/E*e with the exception of
high-pay sub example and entire specimen. The normal of
(EL/E*e) is the 650066.1 and the standard deviation parallels
617684.1. The normal of normal every capita wage development
is 0.202358 furthermore the standard deviation levels with
0.1988373. We have likewise report for the sub test. For the
high pay level nations (as indicated by World Bank 2002
characterization where mid and low pay level nations are
accounted for in the same bunch), the normal of normal every
capita pay development is 0.204 and the standard deviation rises
to 0.124, the normal of (EL/E*e) is the 1081703 and the
standard deviation rises to 656372.1. For the low pay level
nations, the normal of normal every capita wage development is
0. 20 and the standard deviation levels with 0.25, the normal of
(EL/E*e) is the 284834.5 and the standard deviation levels with
226639.3. Both of these measurements are higher in the high-
salary nations. The relationship of the normal of (EL/E*e) and
normal every capita salary development for the entire specimen
is -0.0745 (0.5341). It is -0.2106 (0.2394) for high income level
and it is -0.0660 (0.6899) for the low-wage level.
Financial development is regularly measured as the change
in every capita Gross Domestic Item (GDP). Maintained long
haul financial development at a positive rate is a genuinely later
wonder in mankind's history, the vast majority of it having
happened in the most recent 200 years. As indicated by
Maddison's (2001) evaluations, every capita GDP on the planet
economy was no higher in the year 1000 than in the year 1, and
just 53% higher in 1820 than in 1000, suggesting a normal
yearly development rate of stand out nineteenth of one percent
over the recent 820 year period. Sooner or later around 1820,
the world development rate began to climb, averaging a little
more than one 50% of one percent every year from 1820 to
1870, and topping amid what Maddison calls the "brilliant age",
the period from 1950 to 1973, when it found the middle value of
2.93% every year. By 2000, world every capita GDP had
climbed to more than 8 ½ times its 1820 quality.
Development has been uneven crosswise over time as well
as crosswise over nations. Since 1820, living guidelines in
Western Europe and its branches in North America and the
Antipodes have dashed in front of whatever remains of the
world, except for Japan, in what is frequently alluded to as the
"Extraordinary Divergence". The corresponding crevice in every
capita GDP between the wealthiest gathering of nations and the
poorest gathering (as ordered by Maddison) developed from 3 in
1820 to 19 in 1998. Pritchett (1997) recounts a comparable
story, assessing that the relative crevice between the wealthiest
and poorest nations developed more than five-fold from 1870 to
1990.
Conclusion:
We have proposed that the worldwide contrasts in pay per
capita are best comprehended utilizing an enlarged Solow
development model where physical to human capita degree is
utilized rather their level underway capacity. In our model,
yield is delivered from physical to human capital proportion
what's more work, and that yield is utilized for speculation as a
part of physical to human capital degree and utilization. The
key object of the paper is to explore how well physical to
human capital degree fits in the experimental development
consider other than the merging issue. Despite the fact that not
the relationship help the positive relationship between normal
every capita pay development and EL/E*e, there is a critical
positive relationship between the normal every capita salary
development and changing in EL/E*e. This study gives confirm
that the communication between (K/H) and monetary
development has a tendency to be sure in the example of 36
nations for the years 1990 and 2000. All the more by and large,
our result demonstrates that Solow model predictable with the
worldwide proof regardless of the fact that we utilize (K/H).
Hence, our increasing Solow model says that the distinctions in
sparing (evolving in (EL/E*e)) and populace and persistence
level development should clarify crosscountry contrasts in every
capita wage. The union rate is higher than 2% which is more
noteworthy than general discoveries. The used information may
be steady with the two-segment models of endogenous
development with expansive modification costs for moving
human capital and models of mechanical dispersion. Exploring
the straight relationship between the physical to human capital
proportion and the yield development appears to fit well, which
give just circuitous affirmation for the unevenness impact.
Work Cited
Evans, Paul. “Using Cross-Country Variances to Evaluate
Growth Theories.” Journal of
Economic Dynamics and Control 20 (June-July 1996):
1027-49.
Frankel, Marvin. “The Production Function in Allocation and
Growth: A Synthesis.”
American Economic Review 52 (1962): 995-1022.
Greenwood, Jeremy, and Mehmet Yorukoglu. “1974.” Carnegie-
Rochester ConferenceSeries on Public Policy 46 (June
1997): 49-95.
Maddison, Angus. The World Economy: A Millennial
Perspective. Development Centre
Studies. Paris: OECD, 2001.
micecoo.docx
I'm a postgraduate student in UK
I have A 1500 essay I need your help please
Assessment:
In a popular paper published in 1992 by the Quarterly Journal of
Economics (QJE), Gregory Mankiw, David Romer and David
Weil
(MRW) conclude that:
"international differences in income per capita are best
understood
using an [economic] growth model [where] output is produced
from
physical capital, human capital, and labor, and is used for
investment
in physical capital, investment in human capital, and
consumption."
(Mankiw et al. 1992 , p. 432)
Using the Eviews/GRETL dataset attached, carefully explain the
empirical evidence MRW provide in support in of their thesis.
In
the light of this econometric analysis, do you share the authors’
conclusion above?
Answer in about 1500 words (all included).
Additional information
Deadline: Please submit an electronic copy of your essay on
Study Space
Weight: 50% of portfolio assessment, 22.5% of total marks.
References
[MRW] Mankiw, N.G., Romer, D., Weil, D.N., (1992). A
Contribution
to the Empirics of Economic Growth. The Quarterly Journal
of Economics 107, 407–437. doi:10.2307/2118477
<Available at:
http://qje.oxfordjournals.org/content/107/2/407.abstract >
I can provide you the reference and all data you need to do the
essay with .
You can use one of them (E-views or Gretl) it's you choice
you can find all data on Mankiw et al. (1992)'s Appendix
All data Here with the required reading material p.434-436
page434.pdf
A Contribution to the Empirics of Economic Growth
Author(s): N. Gregory Mankiw, David Romer and David N.
Weil
Source: The Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 107, No. 2
(May, 1992), pp. 407-437
Published by: Oxford University Press
Stable URL: http://www.jstor.org/stable/2118477 .
Accessed: 21/10/2014 08:12
Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the
Terms & Conditions of Use, available at .
http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp
.
JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars,
researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide
range of
content in a trusted digital archive. We use information
technology and tools to increase productivity and facilitate new
forms
of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please
contact [email protected]
.
Oxford University Press is collaborating with JSTOR to
digitize, preserve and extend access to The Quarterly
Journal of Economics.
http://www.jstor.org
This content downloaded from 141.241.43.86 on Tue, 21 Oct
2014 08:12:36 AM
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
http://www.jstor.org/action/showPublisher?publisherCode=oup
http://www.jstor.org/stable/2118477?origin=JSTOR-pdf
http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp
http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp
A CONTRIBUTION TO THE EMPIRICS OF
ECONOMIC GROWTH*
N. GREGORY MANKIW
DAVID ROMER
DAVID N. WEIL
This paper examines whether the Solow growth model is
consistent with the
international variation in the standard of living. It shows that an
augmented Solow
model that includes accumulation of human as well as physical
capital provides an
excellent description of the cross-country data. The paper also
examines the
implications of the Solow model for convergence in standards
of living, that is, for
whether poor countries tend to grow faster than rich countries.
The evidence
indicates that, holding population growth and capital
accumulation constant,
countries converge at about the rate the augmented Solow model
predicts.
INTRODUCTION
This paper takes Robert Solow seriously. In his classic 1956
article Solow proposed that we begin the study of economic
growth
by assuming a standard neoclassical production function with
decreasing returns to capital. Taking the rates of saving and
population growth as exogenous, he showed that these two vari-
ables determine the steady-state level of income per capita. Be-
cause saving and population growth rates vary across countries,
different countries reach different steady states. Solow's model
gives simple testable predictions about how these variables
influ-
ence the steady-state level of income. The higher the rate of
saving,
the richer the country. The higher the rate of population growth,
the poorer the country.
This paper argues that the predictions of the Solow model are,
to a first approximation, consistent with the evidence.
Examining
recently available data for a large set of countries, we find that
saving and population growth affect income in the directions
that
Solow predicted. Moreover, more than half of the cross-country
variation in income per capita can be explained by these two
variables alone.
Yet all is not right for the Solow model. Although the model
correctly predicts the directions of the effects of saving and
*We are grateful to Karen Dynan for research assistance, to
Laurence Ball,
Olivier Blanchard, Anne Case, Lawrence Katz, Robert King,
Paul Romer, Xavier
Sala-i-Martin, Amy Salsbury, Robert Solow, Lawrence
Summers, Peter Temin, and
the referees for helpful comments, and to the National Science
Foundation for
financial support.
? 1992 by the President and Fellows of Harvard College and the
Massachusetts Institute of
Technology.
The Quarterly Journal of Economics, May 1992
This content downloaded from 141.241.43.86 on Tue, 21 Oct
2014 08:12:36 AM
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp
408 QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS
population growth, it does not correctly predict the magnitudes.
In
the data the effects of saving and population growth on income
are
too large. To understand the relation between saving, population
growth, and income, one must go beyond the textbook Solow
model.
We therefore augment the Solow model by including accumu-
lation of human as well as physical capital. The exclusion of
human
capital from the textbook Solow model can potentially explain
why
the estimated influences of saving and population growth appear
too large, for two reasons. First, for any given rate of human-
capital accumulation, higher saving or lower population growth
leads to a higher level of income and thus a higher level of
human
capital; hence, accumulation of physical capital and population
growth have greater impacts on income when accumulation of
human capital is taken into account. Second, human-capital
accu-
mulation may be correlated with saving rates and population
growth rates; this would imply that omitting human-capital
accu-
mulation biases the estimated coefficients on saving and
population
growth.
To test the augmented Solow model, we include a proxy for
human-capital accumulation as an additional explanatory
variable
in our cross-country regressions. We find that accumulation of
human capital is in fact correlated with saving and population
growth. Including human-capital accumulation lowers the esti-
mated effects of saving and population growth to roughly the
values predicted by the augmented Solow model. Moreover, the
augmented model accounts for about 80 percent of the cross-
country variation in income. Given the inevitable imperfections
in
this sort of cross-country data, we consider the fit of this simple
model to be remarkable. It appears that the augmented Solow
model provides an almost complete explanation of why some
countries are rich and other countries are poor.
After developing and testing the augmented Solow model, we
examine an issue that has received much attention in recent
years:
the failure of countries to converge in per capita income. We
argue
that one should not expect convergence. Rather, the Solow
model
predicts that countries generally reach different steady states.
We
examine empirically the set of countries for which
nonconvergence
has been widely documented in past work. We find that once
differences in saving and population growth rates are accounted
for, there is convergence at roughly the rate that the model
predicts.
This content downloaded from 141.241.43.86 on Tue, 21 Oct
2014 08:12:36 AM
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp
THE EMPIRICS OF ECONOMIC GROWTH 409
Finally, we discuss the predictions of the Solow model for
international variation in rates of return and for capital move-
ments. The model predicts that poor countries should tend to
have
higher rates of return to physical and human capital. We discuss
various evidence that one might use to evaluate this prediction.
In
contrast to many recent authors, we interpret the available
evidence on rates of return as generally consistent with the
Solow
model.
Overall, the findings reported in this paper cast doubt on the
recent trend among economists to dismiss the Solow growth
model
in favor of endogenous-growth models that assume constant or
increasing returns to scale in capital. One can explain much of
the
cross-country variation in income while maintaining the
assump-
tion of decreasing returns. This conclusion does not imply, how-
ever, that the Solow model is a complete theory of growth: one
would like also to understand the determinants of saving,
popula-
tion growth, and worldwide technological change, all of which
the
Solow model treats as exogenous. Nor does it imply that
endogenous-
growth models are not important, for they may provide the right
explanation of worldwide technological change. Our conclusion
does imply, however, that the Solow model gives the right
answers
to the questions it is designed to address.
I. THE TEXTBOOK SOLOW MODEL
We begin by briefly reviewing the Solow growth model. We
focus on the model's implications for cross-country data.
A. The Model
Solow's model takes the rates of saving, population growth,
and technological progress as exogenous. There are two inputs,
capital and labor, which are paid their marginal products. We
assume a Cobb-Douglas production function, so production at
time
t is given by
(1) Y(t) = K(t)a(A(t)L(t))l- 0 < a. < 1.
The notation is standard: Y is output, K capital, L labor, and A
the
level of technology. L and A are assumed to grow exogenously
at
rates n and g:
(2) L (t) = L ()ent
(3) A (t) = A (r)ent.
The number of effective units of labor, A (t)L (t), grows at rate
n + g.
This content downloaded from 141.241.43.86 on Tue, 21 Oct
2014 08:12:36 AM
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp
410 QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS
The model assumes that a constant fraction of output, s, is
invested. Defining k as the stock of capital per effective unit of
labor, k = KIAL, and y as the level of output per effective unit
of
labor, y = Y/AL, the evolution of k is governed by
(4) k(t) = sy(t) - (n + g + 8)k (t)
= sk(t)0 - (n + g + 8)k(t),
where 8 is the rate of depreciation. Equation (4) implies that k
converges to a steady-state value k* defined by sk *a = (n + g +
8)k *,
or
(5) k* = [s/(n + g + 5)]1I(1-a)
The steady-state capital-labor ratio is related positively to the
rate
of saving and negatively to the rate of population growth.
The central predictions of the Solow model concern the impact
of saving and population growth on real income. Substituting
(5)
into the production function and taking logs, we find that
steady-
state income per capita is
(6)tl [Ot]ln()gt
(6) In = In A (0) + gt + 1 In(s) - 1 ln(n + g + 8).
Because the model assumes that factors are paid their marginal
products, it predicts not only the signs but also the magnitudes
of
the coefficients on saving and population growth. Specifically,
because capital's share in income (a) is roughly one third, the
model implies an elasticity of income per capita with respect to
the
saving rate of approximately 0.5 and an elasticity with respect
to
n + g + 8 of approximately -0.5.
B. Specification
The natural question to consider is whether the data support
the Solow model's predictions concerning the determinants of
standards of living. In other words, we want to investigate
whether
real income is higher in countries with higher saving rates and
lower in countries with higher values of n + g + 5.
We assume that g and 8 are constant across countries. g
reflects primarily the advancement of knowledge, which is not
country-specific. And there is neither any strong reason to
expect
depreciation rates to vary greatly across countries, nor are there
any data that would allow us to estimate country-specific
deprecia-
tion rates. In contrast, the A(0) term reflects not just technology
This content downloaded from 141.241.43.86 on Tue, 21 Oct
2014 08:12:36 AM
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp
THE EMPIRICS OF ECONOMIC GROWTH 411
but resource endowments, climate, institutions, and so on; it
may
therefore differ across countries. We assume that
lnA(O) = a + E,
where a is a constant and E is a country-specific shock. Thus,
log
income per capita at a given time-time 0 for simplicity-is
(7) In a+ In(s)- In(n+g+8)+E.
Equation (7) is our basic empirical specification in this section.
We assume that the rates of saving and population growth are
independent of country-specific factors shifting the production
function. That is, we assume that s and n are independent of e.
This
assumption implies that we can estimate equation (7) with ordi-
nary least squares (OLS).1
There are three reasons for making this assumption of indepen-
dence. First, this assumption is made not only in the Solow
model,
but also in many standard models of economic growth. In any
model in which saving and population growth are endogenous
but
preferences are isoelastic, s and n are unaffected by E. In other
words, under isoelastic utility, permanent differences in the
level of
technology do not affect saving rates or population growth
rates.
Second, much recent theoretical work on growth has been
motivated by informal examinations of the relationships
between
saving, population growth, and income. Many economists have
asserted that the Solow model cannot account for the
international
differences in income, and this alleged failure of the Solow
model
has stimulated work on endogenous-growth theory. For
example,
Romer [1987, 1989a] suggests that saving has too large an
influence on growth and takes this to be evidence for positive
externalities from capital accumulation. Similarly, Lucas [1988]
asserts that variation in population growth cannot account for
any
substantial variation in real incomes along the lines predicted
by
the Solow model. By maintaining the identifying assumption
that s
and n are independent of E, we are able to determine whether
systematic examination of the data confirms these informal
judg-
ments.
1. If s and n are endogenous and influenced by the level of
income, then
estimates of equation (7) using ordinary least squares are
potentially inconsistent.
In this case, to obtain consistent estimates, one needs to find
instrumental variables
that are correlated with s and n, but uncorrelated with the
country-specific shift in
the production function e. Finding such instrumental variables
is a formidable task,
however.
This content downloaded from 141.241.43.86 on Tue, 21 Oct
2014 08:12:36 AM
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp
412 QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS
Third, because the model predicts not just the signs but also
the magnitudes of the coefficients on saving and population
growth, we can gauge whether there are important biases in the
estimates obtained with OLS. As described above, data on
factor
shares imply that, if the model is correct, the elasticities of Y/L
with respect to s and n + g + 8 are approximately 0.5 and -0.5.
If
OLS yields coefficients that are substantially different from
these
values, then we can reject the joint hypothesis that the Solow
model and our identifying assumption are correct.
Another way to evaluate the Solow model would be to impose
on equation (7) a value of ao derived from data on factor shares
and
then to ask how much of the cross-country variation in income
the
model can account for. That is, using an approach analogous to
"growth accounting," we could compute the fraction of the vari-
ance in living standards that is explained by the mechanism
identified by the Solow model.2 In practice, because we do not
have
exact estimates of factor shares, we do not emphasize this
growth-
accounting approach. Rather, we estimate equation (7) by OLS
and
examine the plausibility of the implied factor shares. The fit of
this
regression shows the result of a growth-accounting exercise per-
formed with the estimated value of a. If the estimated a differs
from the value obtained a priori from factor shares, we can
compare the fit of the estimated regression with the fit obtained
by
imposing the a priori value.
C. Data and Samples
The data are from the Real National Accounts recently
constructed by Summers and Heston [1988]. The data set
includes
real income, government and private consumption, investment,
and population for almost all of the world other than the
centrally
planned economies. The data are annual and cover the period
1960-1985. We measure n as the average rate of growth of the
working-age population, where working age is defined as 15 to
64.3
We measure s as the average share of real investment (including
2. In standard growth accounting, factor shares are used to
decompose growth
over time in a single country into a part explained by growth in
factor inputs and an
unexplained part-the Solow residual-which is usually attributed
to technological
change. In this cross-country analogue, factor shares are used to
decompose
variation in income across countries into a part explained by
variation in saving and
population growth rates and an unexplained part, which could
be attributed to
international differences in the level of technology.
3. Data on the fraction of the population of working age are
from the World
Bank's World Tables and the 1988 World Development Report.
This content downloaded from 141.241.43.86 on Tue, 21 Oct
2014 08:12:36 AM
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp
THE EMPIRICS OF ECONOMIC GROWTH 413
government investment) in real GDP, and Y/L as real GDP in
1985
divided by the working-age population in that year.
We consider three samples of countries. The most comprehen-
sive consists of all countries for which data are available other
than
those for which oil production is the dominant industry.4 This
sample consists of 98 countries. We exclude the oil producers
because the bulk of recorded GDP for these countries represents
the extraction of existing resources, not value added; one should
not expect standard growth models to account for measured
GDP
in these countries.5
Our second sample excludes countries whose data receive a
grade of "D" from Summers and Heston or whose populations in
1960 were less than one million. Summers and Heston use the
"D"
grade to identify countries whose real income figures are based
on
extremely little primary data; measurement error is likely to be
a
greater problem for these countries. We omit the small countries
because the determination of their real income may be
dominated
by idiosyncratic factors. This sample consists of 75 countries.
The third sample consists of the 22 OECD countries with
populations greater than one million. This sample has the
advan-
tages that the data appear to be uniformly of high quality and
that
the variation in omitted country-specific factors is likely to be
small. But it has the disadvantages that it is small in size and
that it
discards much of the variation in the variables of interest.
See the Appendix for the countries in each of the samples and
the data.
D. Results
We estimate equation (7) both with and without imposing the
constraint that the coefficients on ln(s) and ln(n + g + 8) are
equal
in magnitude and opposite in sign. We assume that g + 8 is
0.05;
reasonable changes in this assumption have little effect on the
estimates.6 Table I reports the results.
4. For purposes of comparability, we restrict the sample to
countries that have
not only the data used in this section, but also the data on
human capital described
in Section II.
5. The countries that are excluded on this basis are Bahrain,
Gabon, Iran, Iraq,
Kuwait, Oman, Saudi Arabia, and the United Arab Emirates. In
addition, Lesotho is
excluded because the sum of private and government
consumption far exceeds GDP
in every year of the sample, indicating that labor income from
abroad constitutes an
extremely large fraction of GNP.
6. We chose this value of g + 8 to match the available data. In
U. S. data the
capital consumption allowance is about 10 percent of GNP, and
the capital-output
ratio is about three, which implies that 8 is about 0.03; Romer
[1989a, p. 60]
presents a calculation for a broader sample of countries and
concludes that 8 is
This content downloaded from 141.241.43.86 on Tue, 21 Oct
2014 08:12:36 AM
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp
414 QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS
TABLE I
ESTIMATION OF THE TEXTBOOK SOLOW MODEL
Dependent variable: log GDP per working-age person in 1985
Sample: Non-oil Intermediate OECD
Observations: 98 75 22
CONSTANT 5.48 5.36 7.97
(1.59) (1.55) (2.48)
ln(I/GDP) 1.42 1.31 0.50
(0.14) (0.17) (0.43)
ln(n + g + 8) -1.97 -2.01 -0.76
(0.56) (0.53) (0.84)
H2 0.59 0.59 0.01
s.e.e. 0.69 0.61 0.38
Restricted regression:
CONSTANT 6.87 7.10 8.62
(0.12) (0.15) (0.53)
ln(I/GDP) - ln(n + g + 8) 1.48 1.43 0.56
(0.12) (0.14) (0.36)
1?2 0.59 0.59 0.06
s.e.e. 0.69 0.61 0.37
Test of restriction:
p-value 0.38 0.26 0.79
Implied a 0.60 0.59 0.36
(0.02) (0.02) (0.15)
Note. Standard errors are in parentheses. The investment and
population growth rates are averages for the
period 1960-1985. (g + 8) is assumed to be 0.05.
Three aspects of the results support the Solow model. First,
the coefficients on saving and population growth have the
predicted
signs and, for two of the three samples, are highly significant.
Second, the restriction that the coefficients on ln(s) and
ln(n + g + 8) are equal in magnitude and opposite in sign is not
rejected in any of the samples. Third, and perhaps most
important,
differences in saving and population growth account for a large
fraction of the cross-country variation in income per capita. In
the
regression for the intermediate sample, for example, the
adjusted
R2 is 0.59. In contrast to the common claim that the Solow
model
"explains" cross-country variation in labor productivity largely
by
appealing to variations in technologies, the two readily
observable
about 0.03 or 0.04. In addition, growth in income per capita has
averaged 1.7
percent per year in the United States and 2.2 percent per year in
our intermediate
sample; this suggests that g is about 0.02.
This content downloaded from 141.241.43.86 on Tue, 21 Oct
2014 08:12:36 AM
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp
THE EMPIRICS OF ECONOMIC GROWTH 415
variables on which the Solow model focuses in fact account for
most of the variation in income per capita.
Nonetheless, the model is not completely successful. In par-
ticular, the estimated impacts of saving and labor force growth
are
much larger than the model predicts. The value of a. implied by
the
coefficients should equal capital's share in income, which is
roughly
one third. The estimates, however, imply an a that is much
higher.
For example, the a implied by the coefficient in the constrained
regression for the intermediate sample is 0.59 (with a standard
error of 0.02). Thus, the data strongly contradict the prediction
that a = 1/3.
Because the estimates imply such a high capital share, it is
inappropriate to conclude that the Solow model is successful
just
because the regressions in Table I can explain a high fraction of
the
variation in income. For the intermediate sample, for instance,
when we employ the "growth-accounting" approach described
above and constrain the coefficients to be consistent with an a
of
one third, the adjusted R2 falls from 0.59 to 0.28. Although the
excellent fit of the simple regressions in Table I is promising
for the
theory of growth in general-it implies that theories based on
easily observable variables may be able to account for most of
the
cross-country variation in real income it is not supportive of the
textbook Solow model in particular.
II. ADDING HUMAN-CAPITAL ACCUMULATION TO THE
SOLOW MODEL
Economists have long stressed the importance of human
capital to the process of growth. One might expect that ignoring
human capital would lead to incorrect conclusions: Kendrick
[1976] estimates that over half of the total U. S. capital stock in
1969 was human capital. In this section we explore the effect of
adding human-capital accumulation to the Solow growth model.
Including human capital can potentially alter either the
theoretical modeling or the empirical analysis of economic
growth.
At the theoretical level, properly accounting for human capital
may
change one's view of the nature of the growth process. Lucas
[1988], for example, assumes that although there are decreasing
returns to physical-capital accumulation when human capital is
held constant, the returns to all reproducible capital (human
plus
physical) are constant. We discuss this possibility in Section
III.
At the empirical level, the existence of human capital can alter
the analysis of cross-country differences; in the regressions in
This content downloaded from 141.241.43.86 on Tue, 21 Oct
2014 08:12:36 AM
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp
416 QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS
Table I human capital is an omitted variable. It is this empirical
problem that we pursue in this section. We first expand the
Solow
model of Section I to include human capital. We show how
leaving
out human capital affects the coefficients on physical capital
investment and population growth. We then run regressions
analogous to those in Table I to see whether proxies for human
capital can resolve the anomalies found in the first section.7
A. The Model
Let the production function be
(8) Y(t) = K(t)H(t)P(A(t)L(t))1-a-,
where H is the stock of human capital, and all other variables
are
defined as before. Let Sk be the fraction of income invested in
physical capital and Sh the fraction invested in human capital.
The
evolution of the economy is determined by
(9a) k(t) = sky(t) - (n + g + 8)k(t),
(9b) h(t) = Shy(t) - (n + g + 8)h(t),
where y = Y/AL, k = K/AL, and h = H/AL are quantities per
effective unit of labor. We are assuming that the same
production
function applies to human capital, physical capital, and
consump-
tion. In other words, one unit of consumption can be
transformed
costlessly into either one unit of physical capital or one unit of
human capital. In addition, we are assuming that human capital
depreciates at the same rate as physical capital. Lucas [1988]
models the production function for human capital as fundamen-
tally different from that for other goods. We believe that, at
least
for an initial examination, it is natural to assume that the two
types of production functions are similar.
We assume that a + ,B < 1, which implies that there are
decreasing returns to all capital. (If a + ,B = 1, then there are
constant returns to scale in the reproducible factors. In this
case,
7. Previous authors have provided evidence of the importance of
human capital
for growth in income. Azariadis and Drazen [1990] find that no
country was able to
grow quickly during the postwar period without a highly literate
labor force. They
interpret this as evidence that there is a threshold externality
associated with
human capital accumulation. Similarly, Rauch [1988] finds that
among countries
that had achieved 95 percent adult literacy in 1960, there was a
strong tendency for
income per capita to converge over the period 1950-1985.
Romer [1989b] finds that
literacy in 1960 helps explain subsequent investment and that, if
one corrects for
measurement error, literacy has no impact on growth beyond its
effect on
investment. There is also older work stressing the role of human
capital in
development; for example, see Krueger [1968] and Easterlin
[1981].
This content downloaded from 141.241.43.86 on Tue, 21 Oct
2014 08:12:36 AM
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp
THE EMPIRICS OF ECONOMIC GROWTH 417
there is no steady state for this model. We discuss this
possibility in
Section III.) Equations (9a) and (9b) imply that the economy
converges to a steady state defined by
n + g +
(10)
(*
a k -S a 1/(1-a-)
, n +g+ /
Substituting (10) into the production function and taking logs
gives an equation for income per capita similar to equation (6)
above:
(1 1) In [L(t)| In A(O) + gt -
+
(I ln(n + g + a Y (t)]_
+ Iln(Sk) + In(Sh)
This equation shows how income per capita depends on
population
growth and accumulation of physical and human capital.
Like the textbook Solow model, the augmented model predicts
coefficients in equation (11) that are functions of the factor
shares.
As before, a is physical capital's share of income, so we expect
a
value of a of about one third. Gauging a reasonable value of P,
human capital's share, is more difficult. In the United States the
minimum wage-roughly the return to labor without human
capital-has averaged about 30 to 50 percent of the average wage
in manufacturing. This fact suggests that 50 to 70 percent of
total
labor income represents the return to human capital, or that ,B
is
between one third and one half.
Equation (11) makes two predictions about the regressions
run in Section I, in which human capital was ignored. First,
even if
In (Sh) is independent of the other right-hand side variables, the
coefficient on ln(sk) is greater than a/(1 - a). For example, if a
=
P = 1/3, then the coefficient on ln(sk) would be 1. Because
higher
saving leads to higher income, it leads to a higher steady-state
level
of human capital, even if the percentage of income devoted to
human-capital accumulation is unchanged. Hence, the presence
of
human-capital accumulation increases the impact of physical-
capital accumulation on income.
Second, the coefficient on ln(n + g + 8) is larger in absolute
This content downloaded from 141.241.43.86 on Tue, 21 Oct
2014 08:12:36 AM
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp
418 QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS
value than the coefficient on ln(sk). If a =P = 1/3, for example,
the
coefficient on ln(n + g + 8) would be -2. In this model high
population growth lowers income per capita because the
amounts
of both physical and human capital must be spread more thinly
over the population.
There is an alternative way to express the role of human
capital in determining income in this model. Combining (11)
with
the equation for the steady-state level of human capital given in
(10) yields an equation for income as a function of the rate of
investment in physical capital, the rate of population growth,
and
the level of human capital:
(12) In [L(t) = InA(O) + gt + 1 _ ln(sk)
aL Wi
1 -a n(n + g + 8) + - ln(h*).
Equation (12) is almost identical to equation (6) in Section I. In
that model the level of human capital is a component of the
error
term. Because the saving and population growth rates influence
h *, one should expect human capital to be positively correlated
with the saving rate and negatively correlated with population
growth. Therefore, omitting the human-capital term biases the
coefficients on saving and population growth.
The model with human capital suggests two possible ways to
modify our previous regressions. One way is to estimate the
augmented model's reduced form, that is, equation (11), in
which
the rate of human-capital accumulation ln(sh) is added to the
right-hand side. The second way is to estimate equation (12), in
which the level of human capital In (h *) is added to the right-
hand
side. Notice that these alternative regressions predict different
coefficients on the saving and population growth terms. When
testing the augmented Solow model, a primary question is
whether
the available data on human capital correspond more closely to
the
rate of accumulation (Sh) or to the level of human capital (h).
B. Data
To implement the model, we restrict our focus to human-
capital investment in the form of education-thus ignoring
invest-
ment in health, among other things. Despite this narrowed
focus,
measurement of human capital presents great practical
difficulties.
Most important, a large part of investment in education takes
the
This content downloaded from 141.241.43.86 on Tue, 21 Oct
2014 08:12:36 AM
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp
THE EMPIRICS OF ECONOMIC GROWTH 419
form of forgone labor earnings on the part of students.8 This
problem is difficult to overcome because forgone earnings vary
with
the level of human-capital investment: a worker with little
human
capital forgoes a low wage in order to accumulate more human
capital, whereas a worker with much human capital forgoes a
higher wage. In addition, explicit spending on education takes
place
at all levels of government as well as by the family, which
makes
spending on education hard to measure. Finally, not all
spending
on education is intended to yield productive human capital:
philosophy, religion, and literature, for example, although
serving
in part to train the mind, might also be a form of consumption.9
We use a proxy for the rate of human-capital accumulation (Sh)
that measures approximately the percentage of the working-age
population that is in secondary school. We begin with data on
the
fraction of the eligible population (aged 12 to 17) enrolled in
secondary school, which we obtained from the UNESCO
yearbook.
We then multiply this enrollment rate by the fraction of the
working-age population that is of school age (aged 15 to 19).
This
variable, which we call SCHOOL, is clearly imperfect: the age
ranges in the two data series are not exactly the same, the
variable
does not include the input of teachers, and it completely ignores
primary and higher education. Yet if SCHOOL is proportional
to Sh,
then we can use it to estimate equation (11); the factor of
proportionality will affect only the constant term.10
This measure indicates that investment in physical capital and
population growth may be proxying for human-capital
accumula-
tion in the regressions in Table I. The correlation between
SCHOOL
8. Kendrick [19761 calculates that for the United States in 1969
total gross
investment in education and training was $192.3 billion, of
which $92.3 billion took
the form of imputed compensation to students (tables A-1 and
B-2).
9. An additional problem with implementing the augmented
model is that
"output" in the model is not the same as that measured in the
national income
accounts. Much of the expenditure on human capital is forgone
wages, and these
forgone wages should be included in Y. Yet measured GDP fails
to include this
component of investment spending.
Back-of-the-envelope calculations suggest that this problem is
not quantita-
tively important, however. If human capital accumulation is
completely unmea-
sured, then measured GDP is (1 - Sh)y. One can show that this
measurement
problem does not affect the elasticity of GDP with respect to
physical investment or
population growth. The elasticity of measured GDP with respect
to human capital
accumulation is reduced by Shl(l - Sh) compared with the
elasticity of true GDP
with respect to human capital accumulation. Because the
fraction of a nation's
resources devoted to human capital accumulation is small, this
effect is small. For
example, if a = P = 1/3 and Sh = 0.1, then the elasticity will be
0.9 rather than 1.0.
10. Even under the weaker assumption that ln(sh) is linear in In
(SCHOOL),
we can use the estimated coefficients on ln(sk) and In (n + g +
5) to infer values of a
and P; in this case, the estimated coefficient on In (SCHOOL)
will not have an
interpretation.
This content downloaded from 141.241.43.86 on Tue, 21 Oct
2014 08:12:36 AM
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp
420 QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS
and I/GDP is 0.59 for the intermediate sample, and the
correlation
between SCHOOL and the population growth rate is -0.38.
Thus,
including human-capital accumulation could alter substantially
the estimated impact of physical-capital accumulation and
popula-
tion growth on income per capita.
C. Results
Table II presents regressions of the log of income per capita on
the log of the investment rate, the log of n + g + 8, and the log
of
the percentage of the population in secondary school. The
human-
capital measure enters significantly in all three samples. It also
TABLE II
ESTIMATION OF THE AUGMENTED SOLOW MODEL
Dependent variable: log GDP per working-age person in 1985
Sample: Non-oil Intermediate OECD
Observations: 98 75 22
CONSTANT 6.89 7.81 8.63
(1.17) (1.19) (2.19)
ln(I/GDP) 0.69 0.70 0.28
(0.13) (0.15) (0.39)
ln(n + g + 5) -1.73 -1.50 -1.07
(0.41) (0.40) (0.75)
ln(SCHOOL) 0.66 0.73 0.76
(0.07) (0.10) (0.29)
R2 0.78 0.77 0.24
s.e.e. 0.51 0.45 0.33
Restricted regression:
CONSTANT 7.86 7.97 8.71
(0.14) (0.15) (0.47)
ln(I/GDP) - ln(n + g + 5) 0.73 0.71 0.29
(0.12) (0.14) (0.33)
ln(SCHOOL) - ln(n + g + 5) 0.67 0.74 0.76
(0.07) (0.09) (0.28)
R2 0.78 0.77 0.28
s.e.e. 0.51 0.45 0.32
Test of restriction:
p-value 0.41 0.89 0.97
Implied a 0.31 0.29 0.14
(0.04) (0.05) (0.15)
Implied , 0.28 0.30 0.37
(0.03) (0.04) (0.12)
Note. Standard errors are in parentheses. The investment and
population growth rates are averages for the
period 1960-1985. (g + 8) is assumed to be 0.05. SCHOOL is
the average percentage of the working-age
population in secondary school for the period 1960-1985.
This content downloaded from 141.241.43.86 on Tue, 21 Oct
2014 08:12:36 AM
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp
THE EMPIRICS OF ECONOMIC GROWTH 421
greatly reduces the size of the coefficient on physical capital
investment and improves the fit of the regression compared with
Table I. These three variables explain almost 80 percent of the
cross-country variation in income per capita in the non-oil and
intermediate samples.
The results in Table II strongly support the augmented Solow
model. Equation (11) shows that the augmented model predicts
that the coefficients on In (IIY), In (SCHOOL), and In (n + g +
8)
sum to zero. The bottom half of Table II shows that, for all
three
samples, this restriction is not rejected. The last lines of the
table
give the values of a and ,B implied by the coefficients in the
restricted regression. For non-oil and intermediate samples, a
and
,B are about one third and highly significant. The estimates for
the
OECD alone are less precise. In this sample the coefficients on
investment and population growth are not statistically
significant;
but they are also not significantly different from the estimates
obtained in the larger samples.'1
We conclude that adding human capital to the Solow model
improves its performance. Allowing for human capital
eliminates
the worrisome anomalies-the high coefficients on investment
and
on population growth in our Table I regressions-that arise when
the textbook Solow model is confronted with the data. The
parameter estimates seem reasonable. And even using an
imprecise
proxy for human capital, we are able to dispose of a fairly large
part
of the model's residual variance.
III. ENDOGENOUS GROWTH AND CONVERGENCE
Over the past few years economists studying growth have
turned increasingly to endogenous-growth models. These
models
are characterized by the assumption of nondecreasing returns to
the set of reproducible factors of production. For example, our
model with physical and human capital would become an
endoge-
nous-growth model if a + ,B = 1. Among the implications of this
assumption are that countries that save more grow faster indefi-
nitely and that countries need not converge in income per
capita,
even if they have the same preferences and technology.
11. As we described in the previous footnote, under the weaker
assumption
that ln(sh) is linear in In (SCHOOL), estimates of a and , can be
inferred from the
coefficients on ln(I/GDP) and ln(n + g + 5) in the unrestricted
regression. When we
do this, we obtain estimates of a and , little different from those
reported in
Table II.
This content downloaded from 141.241.43.86 on Tue, 21 Oct
2014 08:12:36 AM
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp
422 QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS
Advocates of endogenous-growth models present them as
alternatives to the Solow model and motivate them by an
alleged
empirical failure of the Solow model to explain cross-country
differences. Barro [1989] presents the argument succinctly:
In neoclassical growth models with diminishing returns, such as
Solow (1956), Cass
(1965) and Koopmans (1965), a country's per capita growth rate
tends to be
inversely related to its starting level of income per person.
Therefore, in the absence
of shocks, poor and rich countries would tend to converge in
terms of levels of per
capita income. However, this convergence hypothesis seems to
be inconsistent with
the cross-country evidence, which indicates that per capita
growth rates are
uncorrelated with the starting level of per capita product.
Our first goal in this section is to reexamine this evidence on
convergence to assess whether it contradicts the Solow model.
Our second goal is to generalize our previous results. To
implement the Solow model, we have been assuming that
countries
in 1985 were in their steady states (or, more generally, that the
deviations from steady state were random). Yet this assumption
is
questionable. We therefore examine the predictions of the aug-
mented Solow model for behavior out of the steady state.
A. Theory
The Solow model predicts that countries reach different steady
states. In Section II we argued that much of the cross-country
differences in income per capita can be traced to differing
determi-
nants of the steady state in the Solow growth model:
accumulation
of human and physical capital and population growth. Thus, the
Solow model does not predict convergence; it predicts only that
income per capita in a given country converges to that country's
steady-state value. In other words, the Solow model predicts
convergence only after controlling for the determinants of the
steady state, a phenomenon that might be called "conditional
convergence."
In addition, the Solow model makes quantitative predictions
about the speed of convergence to steady state. Let y * be the
steady-state level of income per effective worker given by
equation
(11), and let y(t) be the actual value at time t. Approximating
around the steady state, the speed of convergence is given by
d ln(y(t))
(13) dt = X[ln(y*) -ln(y(t))],
where
A = (n + g + a) (1-a -
This content downloaded from 141.241.43.86 on Tue, 21 Oct
2014 08:12:36 AM
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp
THE EMPIRICS OF ECONOMIC GROWTH 423
For example, if a = P = 1/3 and n + g + 8 = 0.06, then the
convergence rate (A) would equal 0.02. This implies that the
economy moves halfway to steady state in about 35 years.
Notice
that the textbook Solow model, which excludes human capital,
implies much faster convergence. If IB = 0, then X becomes
0.04,
and the economy moves halfway to steady state in about
seventeen
years.
The model suggests a natural regression to study the rate of
convergence. Equation (13) implies that
(14) ln(y(t)) = (1 - e-At) ln(y*) + e-At ln(y(0)),
where y(O) is income per effective worker at some initial date.
Subtracting In (y(O)) from both sides,
(15) ln(y(t)) - ln(y(0)) = (1 - e-t) ln(y*) - (1 - e-At) ln(y(0)).
Finally, substituting for y*:
(16) ln(y(t)) - ln(y(0)) = (1 - e-t) ln(sk)
+ (1 - e-t) ln(sh)
- (1 - eAxt) l _ _ In(n + g + 8) - (1 - e-t) ln(y(0)).
Thus, in the Solow model the growth of income is a function of
the
determinants of the ultimate steady state and the initial level of
income.
Endogenous-growth models make predictions very different
from the Solow model regarding convergence among countries.
In
endogenous-growth models there is no steady-state level of
income;
differences among countries in income per capita can persist
indefinitely, even if the countries have the same saving and
population growth rates.12 Endogenous-growth models with a
12. Although we do not explore the issue here, endogenous-
growth models also
make quantitative predictions about the impact of saving on
growth. The models are
typically characterized by constant returns to reproducible
factors of production,
namely physical and human capital. Our model of Section II
with a + , = 1 and g =
0 provides a simple way of analyzing the predictions of models
of endogenous
growth. With these modifications to the model of Section II, the
production function
is Y = AKaH1-a. In this form the model predicts that the ratio
of physical to human
capital, K/H, will converge to SkiSh, and that K, H, and Y will
then all grow at rate
A(Sk)a(Sh )'-a. The derivative of this "steady-state" growth rate
with respect to Sk is
then aA(ShlSk) 1- = atI(KIY). The impact of saving on growth
depends on the
This content downloaded from 141.241.43.86 on Tue, 21 Oct
2014 08:12:36 AM
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp
424 QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS
single sector-those with the "Y = AK" production function-
predict no convergence of any sort. That is, these simple
endoge-
nous-growth models predict a coefficient of zero on y(O) in the
regression in (16). As Barro [1989] notes, however,
endogenous-
growth models with more than one sector may imply
convergence if
the initial income of a country is correlated with the degree of
imbalance among sectors.
Before presenting the results on convergence, we should note
the differences between regressions based on equation (16) and
those we presented earlier. The regressions in Tables I and II
are
valid only if countries are in their steady states or if deviations
from steady state are random. Equation (16) has the advantage
of
explicitly taking into account out-of-steady-state dynamics. Yet,
implementing equation (16) introduces a new problem. If
countries
have permanent differences in their production functions-that is,
different A (O)'s-then these A(O)'s would enter as part of the
error
term and would be positively correlated with initial income.
Hence,
variation inA (0) would bias the coefficient on initial income
toward
zero (and would potentially influence the other coefficients as
well).
In other words, permanent cross-country differences in the
produc-
tion function would lead to differences in initial incomes
uncorre-
lated with subsequent growth rates and, therefore, would bias
the
results against finding convergence.
B. Results
We now test the convergence predictions of the Solow model.
We report regressions of the change in the log of income per
capita
over the period 1960 to 1985 on the log of income per capita in
1960, with and without controlling for investment, growth of
the
working-age population, and school enrollment.
In Table III the log of income per capita appears alone on the
right-hand side. This table reproduces the results of many
previous
authors on the failure of incomes to converge [De Long 1988;
Romer 1987]. The coefficient on the initial level of income per
capita is slightly positive for the non-oil sample and zero for
the
intermediate sample, and for both regressions the adjusted R2 is
exponent on capital in the production function, a, and the
capital-output ratio. In
models in which endogenous growth arises mainly from
externalities from physical
capital, a is close to one, and the derivative of the growth rate
with respect to Sk is
approximately 1 I (KI Y), or about 0.4. In models in which
endogenous growth arises
largely from human capital accumulation and there are no
externalities from
physical capital, the derivative would be about 0.31(KIY), or
about 0.12.
This content downloaded from 141.241.43.86 on Tue, 21 Oct
2014 08:12:36 AM
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp
THE EMPIRICS OF ECONOMIC GROWTH 425
TABLE III
TESTS FOR UNCONDITIONAL CONVERGENCE
Dependent variable: log difference GDP per working-age person
1960-1985
Sample: Non-oil Intermediate OECD
Observations: 98 75 22
CONSTANT -0.266 0.587 3.69
(0.380) (0.433) (0.68)
ln(Y60) 0.0943 -0.00423 -0.341
(0.0496) (0.05484) (0.079)
R2 0.03 -0.01 0.46
s.e.e. 0.44 0.41 0.18
Implied X -0.00360 0.00017 0.0167
(0.00219) (0.00218) (0.0023)
Note. Standard errors are in parentheses. Y60 is GDP per
working-age person in 1960.
essentially zero. There is no tendency for poor countries to
grow
faster on average than rich countries.
Table III does show, however, that there is a significant
tendency toward convergence in the OECD sample. The
coefficient
on the initial level of income per capita is significantly
negative, and
the adjusted R2 of the regression is 0.46. This result confirms
the
findings of Dowrick and Nguyen [1989], among others.
Table IV adds our measures of the rates of investment and
population growth to the right-hand side of the regression. In all
three samples the coefficient on the initial level of income is
now
significantly negative; that is, there is strong evidence of
conver-
gence. Moreover, the inclusion of investment and population
growth rates improves substantially the fit of the regression.
Table
V adds our measure of human capital to the right-hand side of
the
regression in Table IV. This new variable further lowers the
coefficient on the initial level of income, and it again improves
the
fit of the regression.
Figure I presents a graphical demonstration of the effect of
adding measures of population growth and accumulation of
human
and physical capital to the usual "convergence picture," first
presented by Romer [1987]. The top panel presents a scatterplot
for our intermediate sample of the average annual growth rate
of
income per capita from 1960 to 1985 against the log of income
per
capita in 1960. Clearly, there is no evidence that countries that
start off poor tend to grow faster. The second panel of the figure
This content downloaded from 141.241.43.86 on Tue, 21 Oct
2014 08:12:36 AM
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp
426 QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS
TABLE IV
TESTS FOR CONDITIONAL CONVERGENCE
Dependent variable: log difference GDP per working-age person
1960-1985
Sample: Non-oil Intermediate OECD
Observations: 98 75 22
CONSTANT 1.93 2.23 2.19
(0.83) (0.86) (1.17)
ln(Y60) -0.141 -0.228 -0.351
(0.052) (0.057) (0.066)
ln(I/GDP) 0.647 0.644 0.392
(0.087) (0.104) (0.176)
ln(n + g + 8) -0.299 -0.464 -0.753
(0.304) (0.307) (0.341)
R72 0.38 0.35 0.62
s.e.e. 0.35 0.33 0.15
Implied X 0.00606 0.0104 0.0173
(0.00182) (0.0019) (0.0019)
Note. Standard errors are in parentheses. Y60 is GDP per
working-age person in 1960. The investment and
population growth rates are averages for the period 1960-1985.
(g + 8) is assumed to be 0.05.
TABLE V
TESTS FOR CONDITIONAL CONVERGENCE
Dependent variable: log difference GDP per working-age person
1960-1985
Sample: Non-oil Intermediate OECD
Observations: 98 75 22
CONSTANT 3.04 3.69 2.81
(0.83) (0.91) (1.19)
ln(Y60) -0.289 -0.366 -0.398
(0.062) (0.067) (0.070)
ln(I/GDP) 0.524 0.538 0.335
(0.087) (0.102) (0.174)
ln(n + g + 8) -0.505 -0.551 -0.844
(0.288) (0.288) (0.334)
ln(SCHOOL) 0.233 0.271 0.223
(0.060) (0.081) (0.144)
R2 0.46 0.43 0.65
s.e.e. 0.33 0.30 0.15
Implied X 0.0137 0.0182 0.0203
(0.0019) (0.0020) (0.0020)
Note. Standard errors are in parentheses. Y60 is GDP per
working-age person in 1960. The investment and
population growth rates are averages for the period 1960-1985.
(g + 8) is assumed to be 0.05. SCHOOL is the
average percentage of the working-age population in secondary
school for the period 1960-1985.
This content downloaded from 141.241.43.86 on Tue, 21 Oct
2014 08:12:36 AM
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp
THE EMPIRICS OF ECONOMIC GROWTH 427
A. Unconditional
co 6 0 6 0 0 00
(0 ~~~~~0 0 Q) 4 Oo R 0 0O 0
-- ~~00 0 0
2 2 o ? 0 o
-~0 0 Oo0 00
? -2
s 5,5 6,5 7,5 8,5 9.5 10.5
Log output per working age adult: 1960
B. Conditional on saving and population growth
6 ~~ ~~0 0
060 0 0
o0c~ 08 W, 4 _CP O? ?? ?0 8
= 2 0 o D 0
o 020 0
5 s,5 6.5 7, 5 8.5 9.5 10,5
Log output per working age adult:1960
C. Conditional on saving, population growth and human capital
LO
6 0 0
0~~~~~~
2 - ? ? O??b 9 lb8 0~~~~~~
? -2
w 5.5 6.5 7.5 8.5 9.5 10.5
Log output per working age adult: 1960
FIGURE I
Unconditional versus Conditional Convergence
This content downloaded from 141.241.43.86 on Tue, 21 Oct
2014 08:12:36 AM
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp
428 QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS
partials out the logs of the investment rate and (n + g + 5) from
both the income level and growth rate variables. This figure
shows
that if countries did not vary in their investment and population
growth rates, there would be a strong tendency for poor
countries
to grow faster than rich ones. The third panel of Figure I
partials
out our human-capital variable in addition to investment and
population growth rates; the tendency toward convergence is
now
even stronger.
The results in Tables IV and V are notable not only for the
finding of convergence, but also for the rate at which
convergence
occurs. The implied values of X, the parameter governing the
speed
of convergence, are derived from the coefficient on In (Y60).
The
values in Table IV are much smaller than the textbook Solow
model predicts. Yet the estimates in Table V are closer to what
the
augmented Solow model predicts, for two reasons. First, the
augmented model predicts a slower rate of convergence than the
model without human capital. Second, the empirical results
includ-
ing human capital imply a faster rate of convergence than the
empirical results without human capital. Hence, once again, the
inclusion of human capital can help explain some results that
appear anomalous from the vantage point of the textbook Solow
model.
Table VI presents estimates of equation (16) imposing the
restriction that the coefficients on ln(sk), ln(sh), and ln(n + g +
5)
sum to zero. We find that this restriction is not rejected and that
imposing it has little effect on the coefficients. The last lines in
Table VI present the implied values of a and ,. The estimates of
a
range from 0.38 to 0.48, and the estimates of ,B are 0.23 in all
three
samples. Compared with the results in Table II, these
regressions
give a somewhat larger weight to physical capital and a
somewhat
smaller weight to human capital.
In contrast to the results in Tables I through IV, the results for
the OECD sample in Tables V and VI are similar to those for
the
other samples. An interpretation that reconciles the similarity
across samples here and the dissimilarity in the earlier
specifica-
tions is that departures from steady state represent a larger
share
of cross-country variation in income per capita for the OECD
than
for the broader samples. If the OECD countries are far from
their
steady states, then population growth and capital accumulation
have not yet had their full impact on standards of living; hence,
we
obtain lower estimated coefficients and lower R 2's for the
OECD in
This content downloaded from 141.241.43.86 on Tue, 21 Oct
2014 08:12:36 AM
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp
THE EMPIRICS OF ECONOMIC GROWTH 429
TABLE VI
TESTS FOR CONDITIONAL CONVERGENCE, RESTRICTED
REGRESSION
Dependent variable: log difference GDP per working-age person
1960-1985
Sample: Non-oil Intermediate OECD
Observations: 98 75 22
CONSTANT 2.46 3.09 3.55
(0.48) (0.53) (0.63)
ln(Y60) -0.299 -0.372 -0.402
(0.061) (0.067) (0.069)
ln(I/GDP) - ln(n + g + 5) 0.500 0.506 0.396
(0.082) (0.095) (0.152)
ln(SCHOOL) - ln(n + g + 5) 0.238 0.266 0.236
(0.060) (0.080) (0.141)
R2 0.46 0.44 0.66
s.e.e. 0.33 0.30 0.15
Test of restriction:
p-value 0.40 0.42 0.47
ImpliedX 0.0142 0.0186 0.0206
(0.0019) (0.0019) (0.0020)
Implied (x 0.48 0.44 0.38
(0.07) (0.07) (0.13)
Implied 13 0.23 0.23 0.23
(0.05) (0.06) (0.11)
Note. Standard errors are in parentheses. Y60 is GDP per
working-age person in 1960. The investment and
population growth rates are averages for the period 1960-1985.
(g + 5) is assumed to be 0.05. SCHOOL is the
average percentage of the working-age population in secondary
school for the period 1960-1985.
specifications that do not consider out-of-steady-state dynamics.
Similarly, the greater importance of departures from steady
state
for the OECD would explain the finding of greater
unconditional
convergence. We find this interpretation plausible: World War
II
surely caused large departures from the steady state, and it
surely
had larger effects on the OECD than on the rest of the world.
With
a value of X of 0.02, almost half of the departure from steady
state
in 1945 would have remained by the end of our sample in 1985.
Overall, our interpretation of the evidence on convergence
contrasts sharply with that of endogenous-growth advocates. In
particular, we believe that the study of convergence does not
show
a failure of the Solow model. After controlling for those
variables
that the Solow model says determine the steady state, there is
substantial convergence in income per capita. Moreover,
conver-
gence occurs at approximately the rate that the model predicts.
This content downloaded from 141.241.43.86 on Tue, 21 Oct
2014 08:12:36 AM
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp
430 QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS
IV. INTEREST RATE DIFFERENTIALS AND CAPITAL
MOVEMENTS
Recently, several economists, including Lucas [1988], Barro
[1989], and King and Rebelo [1989], have emphasized an
objection
to the Solow model in addition to those we have addressed so
far:
they argue that the model fails to explain either rate-of-return
differences or international capital flows. In the models of
Sections
I and II, the steady-state marginal product of capital, net of
depreciation, is
(17) MPK- 8 = u(n+ g + 8Sk
Thus, the marginal product of capital varies positively with the
population growth rate and negatively with the saving rate.
Because the cross-country differences in saving and population
growth rates are large, the differences in rates of return should
also
be large. For example, if at = 1/3, 8 = 0.03, and g = 0.02, then
the
mean of the steady-state net marginal product is 0.12 in the
intermediate sample, and the standard deviation is 0.08.13
Two related facts seem inconsistent with these predictions.
First, observed differentials in real interest rates appear smaller
than the predicted differences in the net marginal product of
capital. Second, as Feldstein and Horioka [1980] first
documented,
countries with high saving rates have high rates of domestic
investment rather than large current account surpluses: capital
does not flow from high-saving countries to low-saving
countries.
Although these two facts indeed present puzzles to be resolved,
it is premature to view them as a basis for rejecting the Solow
model. The Solow model predicts that the marginal product of
capital will be high in low-saving countries, but it does not
necessarily predict that real interest rates will also be high. One
can infer the marginal product of capital from real interest rates
on
financial assets only if investors are optimizing and capital
markets
are perfect. Both of these assumptions are questionable. It is
13. There is an alternative way of obtaining the marginal
product of capital,
which applies even outside of the steady state but requires an
estimate of I and the
assumption of no country-specific shifts to the production
function. If one assumes
that the returns on human and physical capital are equalized
within each country,
then one can show that the MPK is proportional toy(a+P-
1)/(a+P). Therefore, for the
textbook Solow model in which a = 1/3 and I = 0, the MPK is
inversely proportional
to the square of output. As King and Rebelo [1989] and others
have noted, the
implied differences in rates of return across countries are
incredibly large. Yet if a =
0 = 1/3, then the MPK is inversely proportional to the square
root of output. In this
case, the implied cross-country differences in the MPK are
much smaller and are
similar to those obtained with equation (17).
This content downloaded from 141.241.43.86 on Tue, 21 Oct
2014 08:12:36 AM
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp
THE EMPIRICS OF ECONOMIC GROWTH 431
possible that some of the most productive investments in poor
countries are in public capital, and that the behavior of the
governments of poor countries is not socially optimal. In
addition,
it is possible that the marginal product of private capital is also
high in poor countries, yet those economic agents who could
make
the productive investments do not do so because they face fi-
nancing constraints or because they fear future expropriation.
Some evidence for this interpretation comes from examining
international variation in the rate of profit. If capital earns its
marginal product, then one can measure the marginal product of
capital as
MPK=Ky
That is, the return to capital equals capital's share in income (a)
divided by the capital-output ratio (K/Y). The available
evidence
indicates that capital's share is roughly constant across counties.
Sachs [1979, Table 3] presents factor shares for the G-7
countries.
His figures show that variation in these shares across countries
and over time is small.'4 By contrast, capital-output ratios vary
substantially across countries: accumulating the investment data
from Summers and Heston [1988] to produce estimates of the
capital stock, one finds that low-saving countries have capital-
output ratios near one and high-saving countries have capital-
output ratios near three. Thus, direct measurement of the profit
rate suggests that there is large international variation in the
return to capital.
The available evidence also indicates that expropriation risk is
one reason that capital does not move to eliminate these
differences
in the profit rate. Williams [1975] examines the experience of
foreign investment in developing countries from 1956 to 1972.
He
reports that, during this period, governments nationalized about
19 percent of foreign capital, and that compensation averaged
about 41 percent of book value. It is hard to say precisely how
much
of the observed differences in profit rates this expropriation risk
can explain. Yet, in view of this risk, it would be surprising if
the
14. In particular, there is no evidence that rapid capital
accumulation raises
capital's share. Sachs [1979] reports that Japan's rapid
accumulation in the 1960s
and 1970s, for example, was associated with a rise in labor's
share from 69 percent
in 1962-1964 to 77 percent in 1975-1978. See also Atkinson
[1975, p. 167].
This content downloaded from 141.241.43.86 on Tue, 21 Oct
2014 08:12:36 AM
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp
432 QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS
profit rates were not at least somewhat higher in developing
countries.
Further evidence on rates of return comes from the large
literature on international differences in the return to education.
Psacharopoulos [1985] summarizes the results of studies for
over
60 countries that analyze the determinants of labor earnings
using
micro data. Because forgone wages are the primary cost of
educa-
tion, the rate of return is roughly the percentage increase in the
wage resulting from an additional year of schooling. He reports
that the poorer the country, the larger the return to schooling.
Overall, the evidence on the return to capital appears consis-
tent with the Solow model. Indeed, one might argue that it
supports the Solow model against the alternative of endogenous-
growth models. Many endogenous-growth models assume
constant
returns to scale in the reproducible factors of production; they
therefore imply that the rate of return should not vary with the
level of development. Yet direct measurement of profit rates
and
returns to schooling indicates that the rate of return is much
higher in poor countries.
CONCLUSION
We have suggested that international differences in income per
capita are best understood using an augmented Solow growth
model. In this model output is produced from physical capital,
human capital, and labor, and is used for investment in physical
capital, investment in human capital, and consumption. One
production function that is consistent with our empirical results
is
Y= K1/3H1"31/3.
This model of economic growth has several implications. First,
the elasticity of income with respect to the stock of physical
capital
is not substantially different from capital's share in income.
This
conclusion indicates, in contrast to Romer's suggestion, that
capital receives approximately its social return. In other words,
there are not substantial externalities to the accumulation of
physical capital.
Second, despite the absence of externalities, the accumulation
of physical capital has a larger impact on income per capita than
the textbook Solow model implies. A higher saving rate leads to
higher income in steady state, which in turn leads to a higher
level
of human capital, even if the rate of human-capital
accumulation is
This content downloaded from 141.241.43.86 on Tue, 21 Oct
2014 08:12:36 AM
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp
THE EMPIRICS OF ECONOMIC GROWTH 433
unchanged. Higher saving thus raises total factor productivity as
it
is usually measured. This difference between the textbook
model
and the augmented model is quantitatively important. The text-
book Solow model with a capital share of one third indicates
that
the elasticity of income with respect to the saving rate is one
half.
Our augmented Solow model indicates that this elasticity is one.
Third, population growth also has a larger impact on income
per capita than the textbook model indicates. In the textbook
model
higher population growth lowers income because the available
capital must be spread more thinly over the population of
workers.
In the augmented model human capital also must be spread more
thinly, implying that higher population growth lowers measured
total factor productivity. Again, this effect is important
quantita-
tively. In the textbook model with a capital share of one third,
the
elasticity of income per capita with respect to n + g + 8 is - '/2.
In
our augmented model this elasticity is -2.
Fourth, our model has implications for the dynamics of the
economy when the economy is not in steady state. In contrast to
endogenous-growth models, this model predicts that countries
with similar technologies and rates of accumulation and
population
growth should converge in income per capita. Yet this
convergence
occurs more slowly than the textbook Solow model suggests.
The
textbook Solow model implies that the economy reaches
halfway to
steady state in about 17 years, whereas our augmented Solow
model implies that the economy reaches halfway in about 35
years.
More generally, our results indicate that the Solow model is
consistent with the international evidence if one acknowledges
the
importance of human as well as physical capital. The augmented
Solow model says that differences in saving, education, and
popula-
tion growth should explain cross-country differences in income
per
capita. Our examination of the data indicates that these three
variables do explain most of the international variation.
Future research should be directed at explaining why the
variables taken to be exogenous in the Solow model vary so
much
from country to country. We expect that differences in tax
policies,
education policies, tastes for children, and political stability
will
end up among the ultimate determinants of cross-country differ-
ences. We also expect that the Solow model will provide the
best
framework for understanding how these determinants influence
a
country's level of economic well-being.
This content downloaded from 141.241.43.86 on Tue, 21 Oct
2014 08:12:36 AM
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp
434 QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS
APPENDIX
GDP/ Growth
Sample adult 1960-1985 I/Y SCHOOL
working
Number Country N I 0 1960 1985 GDP age pop
1 Algeria 1 1 0 2485 4371 4.8 2.6 24.1 4.5
2 Angola 1 0 0 1588 1171 0.8 2.1 5.8 1.8
3 Benin 1 0 0 1116 1071 2.2 2.4 10.8 1.8
4 Botswana 1 1 0 959 3671 8.6 3.2 28.3 2.9
5 Burkina Faso 1 0 0 529 857 2.9 0.9 12.7 0.4
6 Burundi 1 0 0 755 663 1.2 1.7 5.1 0.4
7 Cameroon 1 1 0 889 2190 5.7 2.1 12.8 3.4
8 CentralAfr. Rep. 1 0 0 838 789 1.5 1.7 10.5 1.4
9 Chad 1 0 0 908 462 -0.9 1.9 6.9 0.4
10 Congo, Peop. Rep. 1 0 0 1009 2624 6.2 2.4 28.8 3.8
11 Egypt 1 0 0 907 2160 6.0 2.5 16.3 7.0
12 Ethiopia 1 1 0 533 608 2.8 2.3 5.4 1.1
13 Gabon 0 0 0 1307 5350 7.0 1.4 22.1 2.6
14 Gambia, The 0 0 0 799 3.6 18.1 1.5
15 Ghana 1 0 0 1009 727 1.0 2.3 9.1 4.7
16 Guinea 0 0 0 746 869 2.2 1.6 10.9
17 Ivory Coast 1 1 0 1386 1704 5.1 4.3 12.4 2.3
18 Kenya 1 1 0 944 1329 4.8 3.4 17.4 2.4
19 Lesotho 0 0 0 431 1483 6.8 1.9 12.6 2.0
20 Liberia 1 0 0 863 944 3.3 3.0 21.5 2.5
21 Madagascar 1 1 0 1194 975 1.4 2.2 7.1 2.6
22 Malawi 1 1 0 455 823 4.8 2.4 13.2 0.6
23 Mali 1 1 0 737 710 2.1 2.2 7.3 1.0
24 Mauritania 1 0 0 777 1038 3.3 2.2 25.6 1.0
25 Mauritius 1 0 0 1973 2967 4.2 2.6 17.1 7.3
26 Morocco 1 1 0 1030 2348 5.8 2.5 8.3 3.6
27 Mozambique 1 0 0 1420 1035 1.4 2.7 6.1 0.7
28 Niger 1 0 0 539 841 4.4 2.6 10.3 0.5
29 Nigeria 1 1 0 1055 1186 2.8 2.4 12.0 2.3
30 Rwanda 1 0 0 460 696 4.5 2.8 7.9 0.4
31 Senegal 1 1 0 1392 1450 2.5 2.3 9.6 1.7
32 Sierra Leone 1 0 0 511 805 3.4 1.6 10.9 1.7
33 Somalia 1 0 0 901 657 1.8 3.1 13.8 1.1
34 S. Africa 1 1 0 4768 7064 3.9 2.3 21.6 3.0
35 Sudan 1 0 0 1254 1038 1.8 2.6 13.2 2.0
36 Swaziland 0 0 0 817 7.2 17.7 3.7
37 Tanzania 1 1 0 383 710 5.3 2.9 18.0 0.5
38 Togo 1 0 0 777 978 3.4 2.5 15.5 2.9
39 Tunisia 1 1 0 1623 3661 5.6 2.4 13.8 4.3
40 Uganda 1 0 0 601 667 3.5 3.1 4.1 1.1
41 Zaire 1 0 0 594 412 0.9 2.4 6.5 3.6
42 Zambia 1 1 0 1410 1217 2.1 2.7 31.7 2.4
43 Zimbabwe 1 1 0 1187 2107 5.1 2.8 21.1 4.4
This content downloaded from 141.241.43.86 on Tue, 21 Oct
2014 08:12:36 AM
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp
THE EMPIRICS OF ECONOMIC GROWTH 435
APPENDIX
(CONTINUED)
GDP/ Growth
Sample adult 1960-1985 I/Y SCHOOL
working
Number Country N I 0 1960 1985 GDP age pop
44 Afghanistan 0 0 0 1224 1.6 6.9 0.9
45 Bahrain 0 0 0 30.0 12.1
46 Bangladesh 1 1 0 846 1221 4.0 2.6 6.8 3.2
47 Burma 1 1 0 517 1031 4.5 1.7 11.4 3.5
48 Hong Kong 1 1 0 3085 13,372 8.9 3.0 19.9 7.2
49 India 1 1 0 978 1339 3.6 2.4 16.8 5.1
50 Iran 0 0 0 3606 7400 6.3 3.4 18.4 6.5
51 Iraq 0 0 0 4916 5626 3.8 3.2 16.2 7.4
52 Israel 1 1 0 4802 10,450 5.9 2.8 28.5 9.5
53 Japan 1 1 1 3493 13,893 6.8 1.2 36.0 10.9
54 Jordan 1 1 0 2183 4312 5.4 2.7 17.6 10.8
55 Korea, Rep. of 1 1 0 1285 4775 7.9 2.7 22.3 10.2
56 Kuwait 0 0 0 77,881 25,635 2.4 6.8 9.5 9.6
57 Malaysia 1 1 0 2154 5788 7.1 3.2 23.2 7.3
58 Nepal 1 0 0 833 974 2.6 2.0 5.9 2.3
59 Oman 0 0 0 15,584 3.3 15.6 2.7
60 Pakistan 1 1 0 1077 2175 5.8 3.0 12.2 3.0
61 Philippines 1 1 0 1668 2430 4.5 3.0 14.9 10.6
62 Saudi Arabia 0 0 0 6731 11,057 6.1 4.1 12.8 3.1
63 Singapore 1 1 0 2793 14,678 9.2 2.6 32.2 9.0
64 Sri Lanka 1 1 0 1794 2482 3.7 2.4 14.8 8.3
65 Syrian Arab Rep. 1 1 0 2382 6042 6.7 3.0 15.9 8.8
66 Taiwan 0 0 0 8.0 20.7
67 Thailand 1 1 0 1308 3220 6.7 3.1 18.0 4.4
68 U. Arab Emirates 0 0 0 18,513 26.5
69 Yemen 0 0 0 1918 2.5 17.2 0.6
70 Austria 1 1 1 5939 13,327 3.6 0.4 23.4 8.0
71 Belgium 1 1 1 6789 14,290 3.5 0.5 23.4 9.3
72 Cyprus 0 0 0 2948 5.2 31.2 8.2
73 Denmark 1 1 1 8551 16,491 3.2 0.6 26.6 10.7
74 Finland 1 1 1 6527 13,779 3.7 0.7 36.9 11.5
75 France 1 1 1 7215 15,027 3.9 1.0 26.2 8.9
76 Germany, Fed. Rep. 1 1 1 7695 15,297 3.3 0.5 28.5 8.4
77 Greece 1 1 1 2257 6868 5.1 0.7 29.3 7.9
78 Iceland 0 0 0 8091 3.9 29.0 10.2
79 Ireland 1 1 1 4411 8675 3.8 1.1 25.9 11.4
80 Italy 1 1 1 4913 11,082 3.8 0.6 24.9 7.1
81 Luxembourg 0 0 0 9015 2.8 26.9 5.0
82 Malta 0 0 0 2293 6.0 30.9 7.1
83 Netherlands 1 1 1 7689 13,177 3.6 1.4 25.8 10.7
84 Norway 1 1 1 7938 19,723 4.3 0.7 29.1 10.0
This content downloaded from 141.241.43.86 on Tue, 21 Oct
2014 08:12:36 AM
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp
436 QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS
APPENDIX
(CONTINUED)
GDPI Growth
Sample adult 1960-1985 I/Y SCHOOL
working
Number Country N I 0 1960 1985 GDP age pop
85 Portugal 1 1 1 2272 5827 4.4 0.6 22.5 5.8
86 Spain 1 1 1 3766 9903 4.9 1.0 17.7 8.0
87 Sweden 1 1 1 7802 15,237 3.1 0.4 24.5 7.9
88 Switzerland 1 1 1 10,308 15,881 2.5 0.8 29.7 4.8
89 Turkey 1 1 1 2274 4444 5.2 2.5 20.2 5.5
90 United Kingdom 1 1 1 7634 13,331 2.5 0.3 18.4 8.9
91 Barbados 0 0 0 3165 4.8 19.5 12.1
92 Canada 1 1 1 10,286 17,935 4.2 2.0 23.3 10.6
93 Costa Rica 1 1 0 3360 4492 4.7 3.5 14.7 7.0
94 Dominican Rep. 1 1 0 1939 3308 5.1 2.9 17.1 5.8
95 El Salvador 1 1 0 2042 1997 3.3 3.3 8.0 3.9
96 Guatemala 1 1 0 2481 3034 3.9 3.1 8.8 2.4
97 Haiti 1 1 0 1096 1237 1.8 1.3 7.1 1.9
98 Honduras 1 1 0 1430 1822 4.0 3.1 13.8 3.7
99 Jamaica 1 1 0 2726 3080 2.1 1.6 20.6 11.2
100 Mexico 1 1 0 4229 7380 5.5 3.3 19.5 6.6
101 Nicaragua 1 1 0 3195 3978 4.1 3.3 14.5 5.8
102 Panama 1 1 0 2423 5021 5.9 3.0 26.1 11.6
103 Trinidad & Tobago 1 1 0 9253 11,285 2.7 1.9 20.4 8.8
104 United States 1 1 1 12,362 18,988 3.2 1.5 21.1 11.9
105 Argentina 1 1 0 4852 5533 2.1 1.5 25.3 5.0
106 Bolivia 1 1 0 1618 2055 3.3 2.4 13.3 4.9
107 Brazil 1 1 0 1842 5563 7.3 2.9 23.2 4.7
108 Chile 1 1 0 5189 5533 2.6 2.3 29.7 7.7
109 Colombia 1 1 0 2672 4405 5.0 3.0 18.0 6.1
110 Ecuador 1 1 0 2198 4504 5.7 2.8 24.4 7.2
111 Guyana 0 0 0 2761 1.1 32.4 11.7
112 Paraguay 1 1 0 1951 3914 5.5 2.7 11.7 4.4
113 Peru 1 1 0 3310 3775 3.5 2.9 12.0 8.0
114 Surinam 0 0 0 3226 4.5 19.4 8.1
115 Uruguay 1 1 0 5119 5495 0.9 0.6 11.8 7.0
116 Venezuela 1 1 0 10,367 6336 1.9 3.8 11.4 7.0
117 Australia 1 1 1 8440 13,409 3.8 2.0 31.5 9.8
118 Fiji 0 0 0 3634 4.2 20.6 8.1
119 Indonesia 1 1 0 879 2159 5.5 1.9 13.9 4.1
120 New Zealand 1 1 1 9523 12,308 2.7 1.7 22.5 11.9
121 Papua New Guinea 1 0 0 1781 2544 3.5 2.1 16.2 1.5
Note. Growth rates are in percent per year. IIY is investment as
a percentage of GDP, and SCHOOL is the
percentage of the working-age population in secondary school,
both averaged for the period 1960-1985. N, I, and
0 denote the non-oil, intermediate, and OECD samples.
This content downloaded from 141.241.43.86 on Tue, 21 Oct
2014 08:12:36 AM
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp
THE EMPIRICS OF ECONOMIC GROWTH 437
HARVARD UNIVERSITY
UNIVERSITY OF CALIFORNIA AT BERKELEY
BROWN UNIVERSITY
REFERENCES
Atkinson, Anthony, The Economics of Inequality (Oxford:
Clarendon Press, 1975).
Azariadis, Costas, and Allan Drazen, "Threshold Externalities
in Economic
Development," Quarterly Journal of Economics, CV (1990),
501-26.
Barro, Robert J., "Economic Growth in a Cross Section of
Countries," NBER
Working Paper 3120, September 1989.
De Long, J. Bradford, "Productivity Growth, Convergence, and
Welfare: Comment,"
American Economic Review, LXXVIII (1988), 1138-54.
Dowrick, Steve, and Duc-Tho Nguyen, "OECD Comparative
Economic Growth
1950-85: Catch-Up and Convergence," American Economic
Review, LXXIX
(1989),1010-30.
Easterlin, Richard, "Why Isn't the Whole World Developed?"
Journal of Economic
History, XLI (1981),1-20.
Feldstein, Martin, and Charles Horioka, "Domestic Saving and
International
Capital Flows," Economic Journal, XC (1980), 314-29.
Kendrick, John W., The Formation and Stocks of Total Capital
(New York:
Columbia University for NBER, 1976).
King, Robert G., and Sergio T. Rebelo, "Transitional Dynamics
and Economic
Growth in the Neoclassical Model," NBER Working Paper 3185,
November
1989.
Krueger, Anne O., "Factor Endowments and per Capita Income
Differences Among
Countries," Economic Journal, LXXVIII (1968), 641-59.
Lucas, Robert E. Jr., "On the Mechanics of Economic
Development," Journal of
Monetary Economics, XXII (1988), 3-42.
Psacharopoulos, George, "Returns to Education: A Further
International Update
and Implications," Journal of Human Resources, XX (1985),
583-604.
Rauch, James E., "The Question of International Convergence
of per Capita
Consumption: An Euler Equation Approach," mimeo, August
1988, University
of California at San Diego.
Romer, Paul, "Crazy Explanations for the Productivity
Slowdown," NBER Macro-
economicsAnnual, 1987,163-210.
Capital Accumulation in the Theory of Long Run Growth,"
Modern
Business Cycle Theory, Robert J. Barro, ed. (Cambridge, MA:
Harvard Univer-
sity Press, 1989a), pp. 51-127.
"Human Capital and Growth: Theory and Evidence," NBER
Working Paper
3173, November 1989b.
Sachs, Jeffrey D., "Wages, Profit, and Macroeconomic
Adjustment: A Comparative
Study," Brookings Papers on Economic Activity (1979:2), 269-
332.
Solow, Robert M., "A Contribution to the Theory of Economic
Growth," Quarterly
Journal of Economics, LXX (1956), 65-94.
Summers, Robert, and Alan Heston, "A New Set of International
Comparisons of
Real Product and Price Levels Estimates for 130 Countries,
1950-85," Review
of Income and Wealth, XXXIV (1988),1-26.
Williams, M. L., "The Extent and Significance of
Nationalization of Foreign-owned
Assets in Developing Countries, 1956-1972," Oxford Economic
Papers, XXVII
(1975), 260-73.
This content downloaded from 141.241.43.86 on Tue, 21 Oct
2014 08:12:36 AM
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jspArticle
Contentsp. [407]p. 408p. 409p. 410p. 411p. 412p. 413p. 414p.
415p. 416p. 417p. 418p. 419p. 420p. 421p. 422p. 423p. 424p.
425p. 426p. 427p. 428p. 429p. 430p. 431p. 432p. 433p. 434p.
435p. 436p. 437Issue Table of ContentsThe Quarterly Journal of
Economics, Vol. 107, No. 2 (May, 1992), pp. 327-796Front
MatterVoters as Fiscal Conservatives [pp. 327-361]On Diversity
[pp. 363-405]A Contribution to the Empirics of Economic
Growth [pp. 407-437]Job Mobility and the Careers of Young
Men [pp. 439-479]Why is Production More Volatile than Sales?
Theory and Evidence on the Stockout-Avoidance Motive for
Inventory-Holding [pp. 481-510]Asymmetric Tournaments,
Equal Opportunity Laws, and Affirmative Action: Some
Experimental Results [pp. 511-539]Economics of Direct
Legislation [pp. 541-571]Anomalies in Intertemporal Choice:
Evidence and an Interpretation [pp. 573-597]Judging Factor
Abundance [pp. 599-620]Why Do Countries and Industries with
Large Seasonal Cycles Also Have Large Business Cycles? [pp.
621-656]Market Structure and the Nature of Price Rigidity:
Evidence from the Market for Consumer Deposits [pp. 657-
680]Coordination in Split Award Auctions [pp. 681-707]How
Well Does the IS-LM Model Fit Postwar U.S. Data? [pp. 709-
738]Communication in Coordination Games [pp. 739-
771]Financial Assets, Inflation Hedges, and Capital Utilization
in Developing Countries: An Extension of McKinnon's
Complementarity Hypothesis [pp. 773-784]Optimal Financial
Contracting with Ex Post and Ex Ante Observability Problems
[pp. 785-795]Back Matter [pp. 796-796]
Eviews.wf1
Gretl.gdt
Gretl.gdt
18 Nov 2008 16:55
Data imported from Stata file 'mrw.dta', 2014-10-10 14:48
1 1 1 1 0 2485 4371 4.8000001907348633
2.5999999046325684 24.100000381469727 4.5
2 2 1 0 0 1588 1171 0.80000001192092896
2.0999999046325684 5.8000001907348633
1.7999999523162842
3 3 1 0 0 1116 1071 2.2000000476837158
2.4000000953674316 10.800000190734863
1.7999999523162842
4 4 1 1 0 959 3671 8.6000003814697266 3.2000000476837158
28.299999237060547 2.9000000953674316
5 5 1 0 0 529 857 2.9000000953674316 0.89999997615814209
12.699999809265137 0.40000000596046448
6 6 1 0 0 755 663 1.2000000476837158 1.7000000476837158
5.0999999046325684 0.40000000596046448
7 7 1 1 0 889 2190 5.6999998092651367 2.0999999046325684
12.800000190734863 3.4000000953674316
8 8 1 0 0 838 789 1.5 1.7000000476837158 10.5
1.3999999761581421
9 9 1 0 0 908 462 -0.89999997615814209 1.8999999761581421
6.9000000953674316 0.40000000596046448
10 10 1 0 0 1009 2624 6.1999998092651367
2.4000000953674316 28.799999237060547
3.7999999523162842
11 11 1 0 0 907 2160 6 2.5 16.299999237060547 7
12 12 1 1 0 533 608 2.7999999523162842
2.2999999523162842 5.4000000953674316
1.1000000238418579
13 13 0 0 0 1307 5350 7 1.3999999761581421
22.100000381469727 2.5999999046325684
14 14 0 0 0 799 NA 3.5999999046325684 NA
18.100000381469727 1.5
15 15 1 0 0 1009 727 1 2.2999999523162842
9.1000003814697266 4.6999998092651367
16 16 0 0 0 746 869 2.2000000476837158
1.6000000238418579 10.899999618530273 NA
17 17 1 1 0 1386 1704 5.0999999046325684
4.3000001907348633 12.399999618530273
2.2999999523162842
18 18 1 1 0 944 1329 4.8000001907348633
3.4000000953674316 17.399999618530273
2.4000000953674316
QI PLAN PART 22QI PLAN PART 25Running head QI.docx
QI PLAN PART 22QI PLAN PART 25Running head QI.docx
QI PLAN PART 22QI PLAN PART 25Running head QI.docx
QI PLAN PART 22QI PLAN PART 25Running head QI.docx
QI PLAN PART 22QI PLAN PART 25Running head QI.docx
QI PLAN PART 22QI PLAN PART 25Running head QI.docx
QI PLAN PART 22QI PLAN PART 25Running head QI.docx
QI PLAN PART 22QI PLAN PART 25Running head QI.docx
QI PLAN PART 22QI PLAN PART 25Running head QI.docx
QI PLAN PART 22QI PLAN PART 25Running head QI.docx
QI PLAN PART 22QI PLAN PART 25Running head QI.docx
QI PLAN PART 22QI PLAN PART 25Running head QI.docx
QI PLAN PART 22QI PLAN PART 25Running head QI.docx

More Related Content

Similar to QI PLAN PART 22QI PLAN PART 25Running head QI.docx

Table of Contents Section 2 Improving Healthcare Quality from.docx
Table of Contents Section 2 Improving Healthcare Quality from.docxTable of Contents Section 2 Improving Healthcare Quality from.docx
Table of Contents Section 2 Improving Healthcare Quality from.docxperryk1
 
Student 3Reply must be at least 500 words and must also include .docx
Student 3Reply must be at least 500 words and must also include .docxStudent 3Reply must be at least 500 words and must also include .docx
Student 3Reply must be at least 500 words and must also include .docxflorriezhamphrey3065
 
Job Redesign For Expanded HIM Functions Case Study...
Job Redesign For Expanded HIM Functions Case Study...Job Redesign For Expanded HIM Functions Case Study...
Job Redesign For Expanded HIM Functions Case Study...Amanda Hengel
 
1INTERPERSONAL RELATIONS2 1 Aggression and Violence.docx
1INTERPERSONAL RELATIONS2 1 Aggression and Violence.docx1INTERPERSONAL RELATIONS2 1 Aggression and Violence.docx
1INTERPERSONAL RELATIONS2 1 Aggression and Violence.docxfelicidaddinwoodie
 
Utilizing Appropriate Interventions Per.docx
Utilizing Appropriate Interventions Per.docxUtilizing Appropriate Interventions Per.docx
Utilizing Appropriate Interventions Per.docxwrite5
 
RUBRICProductivity Recommendations Last week, you fami.docx
RUBRICProductivity Recommendations Last week, you fami.docxRUBRICProductivity Recommendations Last week, you fami.docx
RUBRICProductivity Recommendations Last week, you fami.docxSUBHI7
 
Interdisciplinary plan proposal
Interdisciplinary plan proposal                                   Interdisciplinary plan proposal
Interdisciplinary plan proposal ADDY50
 
Quality improvement and patient safety in anesthesia
Quality improvement and patient safety in anesthesiaQuality improvement and patient safety in anesthesia
Quality improvement and patient safety in anesthesiaDr. Ravikiran H M Gowda
 
How to Improve Healthcare Reporting Management System.pptx
How to Improve Healthcare Reporting Management System.pptxHow to Improve Healthcare Reporting Management System.pptx
How to Improve Healthcare Reporting Management System.pptxFlutter Agency
 
Centralization of Healthcare Insurance.docx
Centralization of Healthcare Insurance.docxCentralization of Healthcare Insurance.docx
Centralization of Healthcare Insurance.docxwrite31
 
Discussion 1 Leadership Theories in Practice.docx
Discussion 1 Leadership Theories in Practice.docxDiscussion 1 Leadership Theories in Practice.docx
Discussion 1 Leadership Theories in Practice.docxbkbk37
 
Methods Of Program Evaluation. Evaluation Research Is Offered
Methods Of Program Evaluation. Evaluation Research Is OfferedMethods Of Program Evaluation. Evaluation Research Is Offered
Methods Of Program Evaluation. Evaluation Research Is OfferedJennifer Wood
 
GM502 Leadership Theory and Practice I 1 A.docx
 GM502  Leadership Theory and Practice I   1  A.docx GM502  Leadership Theory and Practice I   1  A.docx
GM502 Leadership Theory and Practice I 1 A.docxaryan532920
 
1Quality Improvement Plan TemplateIn this course, you deve.docx
1Quality Improvement Plan TemplateIn this course, you deve.docx1Quality Improvement Plan TemplateIn this course, you deve.docx
1Quality Improvement Plan TemplateIn this course, you deve.docxfelicidaddinwoodie
 
QUALITY IMPROVEMENT PROGRAM .docx
QUALITY IMPROVEMENT PROGRAM                                     .docxQUALITY IMPROVEMENT PROGRAM                                     .docx
QUALITY IMPROVEMENT PROGRAM .docxmakdul
 
Applying Quality Improvement Tools.docx
Applying Quality Improvement Tools.docxApplying Quality Improvement Tools.docx
Applying Quality Improvement Tools.docx4934bk
 
Healthcare quality improvement for meaningful use
Healthcare quality improvement for meaningful useHealthcare quality improvement for meaningful use
Healthcare quality improvement for meaningful useSamantha Haas
 
143382269(1)143382269(2)1433.docx
143382269(1)143382269(2)1433.docx143382269(1)143382269(2)1433.docx
143382269(1)143382269(2)1433.docxdrennanmicah
 
Respond to Marco and Cody by offering additional ideas to overcome.docx
Respond to Marco and Cody by offering additional ideas to overcome.docxRespond to Marco and Cody by offering additional ideas to overcome.docx
Respond to Marco and Cody by offering additional ideas to overcome.docxaudeleypearl
 

Similar to QI PLAN PART 22QI PLAN PART 25Running head QI.docx (20)

Table of Contents Section 2 Improving Healthcare Quality from.docx
Table of Contents Section 2 Improving Healthcare Quality from.docxTable of Contents Section 2 Improving Healthcare Quality from.docx
Table of Contents Section 2 Improving Healthcare Quality from.docx
 
Student 3Reply must be at least 500 words and must also include .docx
Student 3Reply must be at least 500 words and must also include .docxStudent 3Reply must be at least 500 words and must also include .docx
Student 3Reply must be at least 500 words and must also include .docx
 
Job Redesign For Expanded HIM Functions Case Study...
Job Redesign For Expanded HIM Functions Case Study...Job Redesign For Expanded HIM Functions Case Study...
Job Redesign For Expanded HIM Functions Case Study...
 
1INTERPERSONAL RELATIONS2 1 Aggression and Violence.docx
1INTERPERSONAL RELATIONS2 1 Aggression and Violence.docx1INTERPERSONAL RELATIONS2 1 Aggression and Violence.docx
1INTERPERSONAL RELATIONS2 1 Aggression and Violence.docx
 
Program Evaluation
Program EvaluationProgram Evaluation
Program Evaluation
 
Utilizing Appropriate Interventions Per.docx
Utilizing Appropriate Interventions Per.docxUtilizing Appropriate Interventions Per.docx
Utilizing Appropriate Interventions Per.docx
 
RUBRICProductivity Recommendations Last week, you fami.docx
RUBRICProductivity Recommendations Last week, you fami.docxRUBRICProductivity Recommendations Last week, you fami.docx
RUBRICProductivity Recommendations Last week, you fami.docx
 
Interdisciplinary plan proposal
Interdisciplinary plan proposal                                   Interdisciplinary plan proposal
Interdisciplinary plan proposal
 
Quality improvement and patient safety in anesthesia
Quality improvement and patient safety in anesthesiaQuality improvement and patient safety in anesthesia
Quality improvement and patient safety in anesthesia
 
How to Improve Healthcare Reporting Management System.pptx
How to Improve Healthcare Reporting Management System.pptxHow to Improve Healthcare Reporting Management System.pptx
How to Improve Healthcare Reporting Management System.pptx
 
Centralization of Healthcare Insurance.docx
Centralization of Healthcare Insurance.docxCentralization of Healthcare Insurance.docx
Centralization of Healthcare Insurance.docx
 
Discussion 1 Leadership Theories in Practice.docx
Discussion 1 Leadership Theories in Practice.docxDiscussion 1 Leadership Theories in Practice.docx
Discussion 1 Leadership Theories in Practice.docx
 
Methods Of Program Evaluation. Evaluation Research Is Offered
Methods Of Program Evaluation. Evaluation Research Is OfferedMethods Of Program Evaluation. Evaluation Research Is Offered
Methods Of Program Evaluation. Evaluation Research Is Offered
 
GM502 Leadership Theory and Practice I 1 A.docx
 GM502  Leadership Theory and Practice I   1  A.docx GM502  Leadership Theory and Practice I   1  A.docx
GM502 Leadership Theory and Practice I 1 A.docx
 
1Quality Improvement Plan TemplateIn this course, you deve.docx
1Quality Improvement Plan TemplateIn this course, you deve.docx1Quality Improvement Plan TemplateIn this course, you deve.docx
1Quality Improvement Plan TemplateIn this course, you deve.docx
 
QUALITY IMPROVEMENT PROGRAM .docx
QUALITY IMPROVEMENT PROGRAM                                     .docxQUALITY IMPROVEMENT PROGRAM                                     .docx
QUALITY IMPROVEMENT PROGRAM .docx
 
Applying Quality Improvement Tools.docx
Applying Quality Improvement Tools.docxApplying Quality Improvement Tools.docx
Applying Quality Improvement Tools.docx
 
Healthcare quality improvement for meaningful use
Healthcare quality improvement for meaningful useHealthcare quality improvement for meaningful use
Healthcare quality improvement for meaningful use
 
143382269(1)143382269(2)1433.docx
143382269(1)143382269(2)1433.docx143382269(1)143382269(2)1433.docx
143382269(1)143382269(2)1433.docx
 
Respond to Marco and Cody by offering additional ideas to overcome.docx
Respond to Marco and Cody by offering additional ideas to overcome.docxRespond to Marco and Cody by offering additional ideas to overcome.docx
Respond to Marco and Cody by offering additional ideas to overcome.docx
 

More from amrit47

APA, The assignment require a contemporary approach addressing Race,.docx
APA, The assignment require a contemporary approach addressing Race,.docxAPA, The assignment require a contemporary approach addressing Race,.docx
APA, The assignment require a contemporary approach addressing Race,.docxamrit47
 
APA style and all questions answered ( no min page requirements) .docx
APA style and all questions answered ( no min page requirements) .docxAPA style and all questions answered ( no min page requirements) .docx
APA style and all questions answered ( no min page requirements) .docxamrit47
 
Apa format1-2 paragraphsreferences It is often said th.docx
Apa format1-2 paragraphsreferences It is often said th.docxApa format1-2 paragraphsreferences It is often said th.docx
Apa format1-2 paragraphsreferences It is often said th.docxamrit47
 
APA format2-3 pages, double-spaced1. Choose a speech to review. It.docx
APA format2-3 pages, double-spaced1. Choose a speech to review. It.docxAPA format2-3 pages, double-spaced1. Choose a speech to review. It.docx
APA format2-3 pages, double-spaced1. Choose a speech to review. It.docxamrit47
 
APA format  httpsapastyle.apa.orghttpsowl.purd.docx
APA format     httpsapastyle.apa.orghttpsowl.purd.docxAPA format     httpsapastyle.apa.orghttpsowl.purd.docx
APA format  httpsapastyle.apa.orghttpsowl.purd.docxamrit47
 
APA format2-3 pages, double-spaced1. Choose a speech to review. .docx
APA format2-3 pages, double-spaced1. Choose a speech to review. .docxAPA format2-3 pages, double-spaced1. Choose a speech to review. .docx
APA format2-3 pages, double-spaced1. Choose a speech to review. .docxamrit47
 
APA Formatting AssignmentUse the information below to create.docx
APA Formatting AssignmentUse the information below to create.docxAPA Formatting AssignmentUse the information below to create.docx
APA Formatting AssignmentUse the information below to create.docxamrit47
 
APA style300 words10 maximum plagiarism  Mrs. Smith was.docx
APA style300 words10 maximum plagiarism  Mrs. Smith was.docxAPA style300 words10 maximum plagiarism  Mrs. Smith was.docx
APA style300 words10 maximum plagiarism  Mrs. Smith was.docxamrit47
 
APA format1. What are the three most important takeawayslessons.docx
APA format1. What are the three most important takeawayslessons.docxAPA format1. What are the three most important takeawayslessons.docx
APA format1. What are the three most important takeawayslessons.docxamrit47
 
APA General Format Summary APA (American Psychological.docx
APA General Format Summary APA (American Psychological.docxAPA General Format Summary APA (American Psychological.docx
APA General Format Summary APA (American Psychological.docxamrit47
 
Appearance When I watched the video of myself, I felt that my b.docx
Appearance When I watched the video of myself, I felt that my b.docxAppearance When I watched the video of myself, I felt that my b.docx
Appearance When I watched the video of myself, I felt that my b.docxamrit47
 
apa format1-2 paragraphsreferencesFor this week’s .docx
apa format1-2 paragraphsreferencesFor this week’s .docxapa format1-2 paragraphsreferencesFor this week’s .docx
apa format1-2 paragraphsreferencesFor this week’s .docxamrit47
 
APA Format, with 2 references for each question and an assignment..docx
APA Format, with 2 references for each question and an assignment..docxAPA Format, with 2 references for each question and an assignment..docx
APA Format, with 2 references for each question and an assignment..docxamrit47
 
APA-formatted 8-10 page research paper which examines the potential .docx
APA-formatted 8-10 page research paper which examines the potential .docxAPA-formatted 8-10 page research paper which examines the potential .docx
APA-formatted 8-10 page research paper which examines the potential .docxamrit47
 
APA    STYLE 1.Define the terms multiple disabilities and .docx
APA    STYLE 1.Define the terms multiple disabilities and .docxAPA    STYLE 1.Define the terms multiple disabilities and .docx
APA    STYLE 1.Define the terms multiple disabilities and .docxamrit47
 
APA STYLE  follow this textbook answer should be summarize for t.docx
APA STYLE  follow this textbook answer should be summarize for t.docxAPA STYLE  follow this textbook answer should be summarize for t.docx
APA STYLE  follow this textbook answer should be summarize for t.docxamrit47
 
APA7Page length 3-4, including Title Page and Reference Pag.docx
APA7Page length 3-4, including Title Page and Reference Pag.docxAPA7Page length 3-4, including Title Page and Reference Pag.docx
APA7Page length 3-4, including Title Page and Reference Pag.docxamrit47
 
APA format, 2 pagesThree general sections 1. an article s.docx
APA format, 2 pagesThree general sections 1. an article s.docxAPA format, 2 pagesThree general sections 1. an article s.docx
APA format, 2 pagesThree general sections 1. an article s.docxamrit47
 
APA Style with minimum of 450 words, with annotations, quotation.docx
APA Style with minimum of 450 words, with annotations, quotation.docxAPA Style with minimum of 450 words, with annotations, quotation.docx
APA Style with minimum of 450 words, with annotations, quotation.docxamrit47
 
APA FORMAT1.  What are the three most important takeawayslesson.docx
APA FORMAT1.  What are the three most important takeawayslesson.docxAPA FORMAT1.  What are the three most important takeawayslesson.docx
APA FORMAT1.  What are the three most important takeawayslesson.docxamrit47
 

More from amrit47 (20)

APA, The assignment require a contemporary approach addressing Race,.docx
APA, The assignment require a contemporary approach addressing Race,.docxAPA, The assignment require a contemporary approach addressing Race,.docx
APA, The assignment require a contemporary approach addressing Race,.docx
 
APA style and all questions answered ( no min page requirements) .docx
APA style and all questions answered ( no min page requirements) .docxAPA style and all questions answered ( no min page requirements) .docx
APA style and all questions answered ( no min page requirements) .docx
 
Apa format1-2 paragraphsreferences It is often said th.docx
Apa format1-2 paragraphsreferences It is often said th.docxApa format1-2 paragraphsreferences It is often said th.docx
Apa format1-2 paragraphsreferences It is often said th.docx
 
APA format2-3 pages, double-spaced1. Choose a speech to review. It.docx
APA format2-3 pages, double-spaced1. Choose a speech to review. It.docxAPA format2-3 pages, double-spaced1. Choose a speech to review. It.docx
APA format2-3 pages, double-spaced1. Choose a speech to review. It.docx
 
APA format  httpsapastyle.apa.orghttpsowl.purd.docx
APA format     httpsapastyle.apa.orghttpsowl.purd.docxAPA format     httpsapastyle.apa.orghttpsowl.purd.docx
APA format  httpsapastyle.apa.orghttpsowl.purd.docx
 
APA format2-3 pages, double-spaced1. Choose a speech to review. .docx
APA format2-3 pages, double-spaced1. Choose a speech to review. .docxAPA format2-3 pages, double-spaced1. Choose a speech to review. .docx
APA format2-3 pages, double-spaced1. Choose a speech to review. .docx
 
APA Formatting AssignmentUse the information below to create.docx
APA Formatting AssignmentUse the information below to create.docxAPA Formatting AssignmentUse the information below to create.docx
APA Formatting AssignmentUse the information below to create.docx
 
APA style300 words10 maximum plagiarism  Mrs. Smith was.docx
APA style300 words10 maximum plagiarism  Mrs. Smith was.docxAPA style300 words10 maximum plagiarism  Mrs. Smith was.docx
APA style300 words10 maximum plagiarism  Mrs. Smith was.docx
 
APA format1. What are the three most important takeawayslessons.docx
APA format1. What are the three most important takeawayslessons.docxAPA format1. What are the three most important takeawayslessons.docx
APA format1. What are the three most important takeawayslessons.docx
 
APA General Format Summary APA (American Psychological.docx
APA General Format Summary APA (American Psychological.docxAPA General Format Summary APA (American Psychological.docx
APA General Format Summary APA (American Psychological.docx
 
Appearance When I watched the video of myself, I felt that my b.docx
Appearance When I watched the video of myself, I felt that my b.docxAppearance When I watched the video of myself, I felt that my b.docx
Appearance When I watched the video of myself, I felt that my b.docx
 
apa format1-2 paragraphsreferencesFor this week’s .docx
apa format1-2 paragraphsreferencesFor this week’s .docxapa format1-2 paragraphsreferencesFor this week’s .docx
apa format1-2 paragraphsreferencesFor this week’s .docx
 
APA Format, with 2 references for each question and an assignment..docx
APA Format, with 2 references for each question and an assignment..docxAPA Format, with 2 references for each question and an assignment..docx
APA Format, with 2 references for each question and an assignment..docx
 
APA-formatted 8-10 page research paper which examines the potential .docx
APA-formatted 8-10 page research paper which examines the potential .docxAPA-formatted 8-10 page research paper which examines the potential .docx
APA-formatted 8-10 page research paper which examines the potential .docx
 
APA    STYLE 1.Define the terms multiple disabilities and .docx
APA    STYLE 1.Define the terms multiple disabilities and .docxAPA    STYLE 1.Define the terms multiple disabilities and .docx
APA    STYLE 1.Define the terms multiple disabilities and .docx
 
APA STYLE  follow this textbook answer should be summarize for t.docx
APA STYLE  follow this textbook answer should be summarize for t.docxAPA STYLE  follow this textbook answer should be summarize for t.docx
APA STYLE  follow this textbook answer should be summarize for t.docx
 
APA7Page length 3-4, including Title Page and Reference Pag.docx
APA7Page length 3-4, including Title Page and Reference Pag.docxAPA7Page length 3-4, including Title Page and Reference Pag.docx
APA7Page length 3-4, including Title Page and Reference Pag.docx
 
APA format, 2 pagesThree general sections 1. an article s.docx
APA format, 2 pagesThree general sections 1. an article s.docxAPA format, 2 pagesThree general sections 1. an article s.docx
APA format, 2 pagesThree general sections 1. an article s.docx
 
APA Style with minimum of 450 words, with annotations, quotation.docx
APA Style with minimum of 450 words, with annotations, quotation.docxAPA Style with minimum of 450 words, with annotations, quotation.docx
APA Style with minimum of 450 words, with annotations, quotation.docx
 
APA FORMAT1.  What are the three most important takeawayslesson.docx
APA FORMAT1.  What are the three most important takeawayslesson.docxAPA FORMAT1.  What are the three most important takeawayslesson.docx
APA FORMAT1.  What are the three most important takeawayslesson.docx
 

Recently uploaded

Industrial Policy - 1948, 1956, 1973, 1977, 1980, 1991
Industrial Policy - 1948, 1956, 1973, 1977, 1980, 1991Industrial Policy - 1948, 1956, 1973, 1977, 1980, 1991
Industrial Policy - 1948, 1956, 1973, 1977, 1980, 1991RKavithamani
 
18-04-UA_REPORT_MEDIALITERAСY_INDEX-DM_23-1-final-eng.pdf
18-04-UA_REPORT_MEDIALITERAСY_INDEX-DM_23-1-final-eng.pdf18-04-UA_REPORT_MEDIALITERAСY_INDEX-DM_23-1-final-eng.pdf
18-04-UA_REPORT_MEDIALITERAСY_INDEX-DM_23-1-final-eng.pdfssuser54595a
 
Kisan Call Centre - To harness potential of ICT in Agriculture by answer farm...
Kisan Call Centre - To harness potential of ICT in Agriculture by answer farm...Kisan Call Centre - To harness potential of ICT in Agriculture by answer farm...
Kisan Call Centre - To harness potential of ICT in Agriculture by answer farm...Krashi Coaching
 
Paris 2024 Olympic Geographies - an activity
Paris 2024 Olympic Geographies - an activityParis 2024 Olympic Geographies - an activity
Paris 2024 Olympic Geographies - an activityGeoBlogs
 
How to Make a Pirate ship Primary Education.pptx
How to Make a Pirate ship Primary Education.pptxHow to Make a Pirate ship Primary Education.pptx
How to Make a Pirate ship Primary Education.pptxmanuelaromero2013
 
Presentation by Andreas Schleicher Tackling the School Absenteeism Crisis 30 ...
Presentation by Andreas Schleicher Tackling the School Absenteeism Crisis 30 ...Presentation by Andreas Schleicher Tackling the School Absenteeism Crisis 30 ...
Presentation by Andreas Schleicher Tackling the School Absenteeism Crisis 30 ...EduSkills OECD
 
Organic Name Reactions for the students and aspirants of Chemistry12th.pptx
Organic Name Reactions  for the students and aspirants of Chemistry12th.pptxOrganic Name Reactions  for the students and aspirants of Chemistry12th.pptx
Organic Name Reactions for the students and aspirants of Chemistry12th.pptxVS Mahajan Coaching Centre
 
The Most Excellent Way | 1 Corinthians 13
The Most Excellent Way | 1 Corinthians 13The Most Excellent Way | 1 Corinthians 13
The Most Excellent Way | 1 Corinthians 13Steve Thomason
 
SOCIAL AND HISTORICAL CONTEXT - LFTVD.pptx
SOCIAL AND HISTORICAL CONTEXT - LFTVD.pptxSOCIAL AND HISTORICAL CONTEXT - LFTVD.pptx
SOCIAL AND HISTORICAL CONTEXT - LFTVD.pptxiammrhaywood
 
Accessible design: Minimum effort, maximum impact
Accessible design: Minimum effort, maximum impactAccessible design: Minimum effort, maximum impact
Accessible design: Minimum effort, maximum impactdawncurless
 
URLs and Routing in the Odoo 17 Website App
URLs and Routing in the Odoo 17 Website AppURLs and Routing in the Odoo 17 Website App
URLs and Routing in the Odoo 17 Website AppCeline George
 
Mastering the Unannounced Regulatory Inspection
Mastering the Unannounced Regulatory InspectionMastering the Unannounced Regulatory Inspection
Mastering the Unannounced Regulatory InspectionSafetyChain Software
 
Measures of Central Tendency: Mean, Median and Mode
Measures of Central Tendency: Mean, Median and ModeMeasures of Central Tendency: Mean, Median and Mode
Measures of Central Tendency: Mean, Median and ModeThiyagu K
 
Software Engineering Methodologies (overview)
Software Engineering Methodologies (overview)Software Engineering Methodologies (overview)
Software Engineering Methodologies (overview)eniolaolutunde
 
Z Score,T Score, Percential Rank and Box Plot Graph
Z Score,T Score, Percential Rank and Box Plot GraphZ Score,T Score, Percential Rank and Box Plot Graph
Z Score,T Score, Percential Rank and Box Plot GraphThiyagu K
 
microwave assisted reaction. General introduction
microwave assisted reaction. General introductionmicrowave assisted reaction. General introduction
microwave assisted reaction. General introductionMaksud Ahmed
 
Introduction to ArtificiaI Intelligence in Higher Education
Introduction to ArtificiaI Intelligence in Higher EducationIntroduction to ArtificiaI Intelligence in Higher Education
Introduction to ArtificiaI Intelligence in Higher Educationpboyjonauth
 

Recently uploaded (20)

Mattingly "AI & Prompt Design: Structured Data, Assistants, & RAG"
Mattingly "AI & Prompt Design: Structured Data, Assistants, & RAG"Mattingly "AI & Prompt Design: Structured Data, Assistants, & RAG"
Mattingly "AI & Prompt Design: Structured Data, Assistants, & RAG"
 
TataKelola dan KamSiber Kecerdasan Buatan v022.pdf
TataKelola dan KamSiber Kecerdasan Buatan v022.pdfTataKelola dan KamSiber Kecerdasan Buatan v022.pdf
TataKelola dan KamSiber Kecerdasan Buatan v022.pdf
 
Industrial Policy - 1948, 1956, 1973, 1977, 1980, 1991
Industrial Policy - 1948, 1956, 1973, 1977, 1980, 1991Industrial Policy - 1948, 1956, 1973, 1977, 1980, 1991
Industrial Policy - 1948, 1956, 1973, 1977, 1980, 1991
 
18-04-UA_REPORT_MEDIALITERAСY_INDEX-DM_23-1-final-eng.pdf
18-04-UA_REPORT_MEDIALITERAСY_INDEX-DM_23-1-final-eng.pdf18-04-UA_REPORT_MEDIALITERAСY_INDEX-DM_23-1-final-eng.pdf
18-04-UA_REPORT_MEDIALITERAСY_INDEX-DM_23-1-final-eng.pdf
 
Mattingly "AI & Prompt Design: The Basics of Prompt Design"
Mattingly "AI & Prompt Design: The Basics of Prompt Design"Mattingly "AI & Prompt Design: The Basics of Prompt Design"
Mattingly "AI & Prompt Design: The Basics of Prompt Design"
 
Kisan Call Centre - To harness potential of ICT in Agriculture by answer farm...
Kisan Call Centre - To harness potential of ICT in Agriculture by answer farm...Kisan Call Centre - To harness potential of ICT in Agriculture by answer farm...
Kisan Call Centre - To harness potential of ICT in Agriculture by answer farm...
 
Paris 2024 Olympic Geographies - an activity
Paris 2024 Olympic Geographies - an activityParis 2024 Olympic Geographies - an activity
Paris 2024 Olympic Geographies - an activity
 
How to Make a Pirate ship Primary Education.pptx
How to Make a Pirate ship Primary Education.pptxHow to Make a Pirate ship Primary Education.pptx
How to Make a Pirate ship Primary Education.pptx
 
Presentation by Andreas Schleicher Tackling the School Absenteeism Crisis 30 ...
Presentation by Andreas Schleicher Tackling the School Absenteeism Crisis 30 ...Presentation by Andreas Schleicher Tackling the School Absenteeism Crisis 30 ...
Presentation by Andreas Schleicher Tackling the School Absenteeism Crisis 30 ...
 
Organic Name Reactions for the students and aspirants of Chemistry12th.pptx
Organic Name Reactions  for the students and aspirants of Chemistry12th.pptxOrganic Name Reactions  for the students and aspirants of Chemistry12th.pptx
Organic Name Reactions for the students and aspirants of Chemistry12th.pptx
 
The Most Excellent Way | 1 Corinthians 13
The Most Excellent Way | 1 Corinthians 13The Most Excellent Way | 1 Corinthians 13
The Most Excellent Way | 1 Corinthians 13
 
SOCIAL AND HISTORICAL CONTEXT - LFTVD.pptx
SOCIAL AND HISTORICAL CONTEXT - LFTVD.pptxSOCIAL AND HISTORICAL CONTEXT - LFTVD.pptx
SOCIAL AND HISTORICAL CONTEXT - LFTVD.pptx
 
Accessible design: Minimum effort, maximum impact
Accessible design: Minimum effort, maximum impactAccessible design: Minimum effort, maximum impact
Accessible design: Minimum effort, maximum impact
 
URLs and Routing in the Odoo 17 Website App
URLs and Routing in the Odoo 17 Website AppURLs and Routing in the Odoo 17 Website App
URLs and Routing in the Odoo 17 Website App
 
Mastering the Unannounced Regulatory Inspection
Mastering the Unannounced Regulatory InspectionMastering the Unannounced Regulatory Inspection
Mastering the Unannounced Regulatory Inspection
 
Measures of Central Tendency: Mean, Median and Mode
Measures of Central Tendency: Mean, Median and ModeMeasures of Central Tendency: Mean, Median and Mode
Measures of Central Tendency: Mean, Median and Mode
 
Software Engineering Methodologies (overview)
Software Engineering Methodologies (overview)Software Engineering Methodologies (overview)
Software Engineering Methodologies (overview)
 
Z Score,T Score, Percential Rank and Box Plot Graph
Z Score,T Score, Percential Rank and Box Plot GraphZ Score,T Score, Percential Rank and Box Plot Graph
Z Score,T Score, Percential Rank and Box Plot Graph
 
microwave assisted reaction. General introduction
microwave assisted reaction. General introductionmicrowave assisted reaction. General introduction
microwave assisted reaction. General introduction
 
Introduction to ArtificiaI Intelligence in Higher Education
Introduction to ArtificiaI Intelligence in Higher EducationIntroduction to ArtificiaI Intelligence in Higher Education
Introduction to ArtificiaI Intelligence in Higher Education
 

QI PLAN PART 22QI PLAN PART 25Running head QI.docx

  • 1. QI PLAN PART 2 2 QI PLAN PART 2 5 Running head: QI PLAN PART 2 1 QI Plan Part 2 This methodology is chosen because in performance improvement it entails satisfactory of the patients, the process of delivery and improvement of the processes. The quality improvement (QI) is identified to focus on bringing out the gap in between the current levels of quality and the expected quality levels. The Quality Improvement uses the tools for managing quality together with the principles towards understanding and address systems deficiencies hence improving or re-designing efficiently the effective healthcare processes (Scales, 2014). Moreover, setting up a Quality Improvement process is termed to be an easy task but in order to integrate these processes in day to day activities, there have to be effective implementation via the leadership dedication, empowering of the employees, the healthy culture of business and the effectiveness of strategic planning that management has been embraced along with the desired performances. The information technology applications include the Hospital
  • 2. Admission Risk Prediction (HARP) and the Episheet. In terms of improving the performance area, the HARP aims in predicting the future events, creating the intervention mechanism to the health care providers and generating the information regarding patient risk within future framework (Scales, 2014). The other application tool named Episheet is a qualitative tool which is applied in epidemiologic data analysis. It will help improve the performance area through gathering of the information and ensuring the priority of the healthcare organization. In order to meet the performance improvement plan, innovation technology has to be considered in all applications. The IT applications are applied in an object oriented technology as well as in a computerized patient records systems and might also be used in the specific components of IT. Certainly, the object oriented technology would ensure that all different systems within the organization are connected and proper management (Hermann, 2005). The information technology entails the management of the patient’s records through computerization in order to prevent loss or from being accessed by the illegitimate persons. Furthermore, this aspect explores that for the use of the specific IT components, it is quite easy to monitor an organizational quality performance because the organization does not need change from the component directly to the other when delivering its services. The quality indicators are identified as the guide to evaluation of the appropriate performance of an organization. The reason is that the performance is always evaluated continuously and at last at the end of the projects in a way that the organization carries out the process. Therefore, the benchmarks are termed as the programs as well as the operations which are set in order to make assessment of organizational performances. It is ideally achieved through some of the standards and run trial tests (Scales, 2014). In quality improvement, this enables in determining how effectively procedures which are being adhered to by an organization are analyzed. It is therefore
  • 3. through these aspects that the performance of the information technology within the organization is identified to have been reviewed. On the other side, milestones mark the end of the project, an end of a certain stage or particular step. Moreover, the performance is progressively monitored, improved and improved after milestones. It is aligned with the performance mission, vision and the strategic plan in a way that healthcare’s provision targets goal by ensuring that each patient receives the quality health care services. The mission, vision and the strategic plan is to provide the appropriate satisfactory services to patients and work towards diverse population. The performance improvement is aligned with the plans of the health care organization through quality improvement and the patient’s satisfactory which have to be achieved. These tools have similarity like; they are used in evaluating the effectiveness of the health care services in healthcare organization settings. They attributed to the quality of services provided by the healthcare organization through directing the organization towards improvement on their services. Child Health Care Quality measurement is known to be much more concerned with children health quality. Meaning that, it contains information and also tools that can be used to evaluate the healthcare quality for children. It is based in the healthcare organization and the information that is evaluated is signifies health care organization (Hermann, 2005). The ambulatory care is used provision as well as evaluation of the health care organization readiness. It presents the tests regarding health quality preparedness along introducing a task. Contrary to the child healthcare Quality toolbox, the ambulatory care tool obtains information from people around.
  • 4. References Gao, Q. (2014). A Procedural Framework for Trans boundary Water Management in the Mekong River Basin Shared Mekong for a Common Future. Hermann, R. (2005). Improving Mental Healthcare: A Guide to Measurement-Based Quality Improvement. Arlington: American Psychiatric Pub. Scales, D. C., & Rubenfeld, G. D. (2014). The organization of critical care: An evidence-based approach to improving quality. What is written on the file you have attached is not what I expected , there are some issues: 1- you did not mention the reference that I gave you, that should be mentioned and all the essay must be based on (MRW). 2- No equations on the essay except one basic equation about education. You can find on the reference there are many equations are related to the subject. 3- You have to focus on the data between p.436-436 analyze them with interpretation and explanation. 4- No problem if you use other references related to the main reference. You can use quotations and citations as well. In the equation you can use a special format for that on
  • 5. (Microsoft Word) the way that you wrote the equations the last time is not acceptable. I need the code file as wellalso; you have to use Harvard style with the references Regards Kindly do not forget to put: - Brief introduction about the subject - Brief conclusion - Equations - Graphs if you could - Citations - Quotations with page numbers after the date - List of references in the last page of the essay - 1500 words is the maximum number do not make it more Professional work are needed I'm a postgraduate student Please answer the question carefully this time I paid a lot of money for a good work and that was not. PLEASE SEE NEXT PAGE Introduction: The physical to human capital proportion is composed in expanding work Solow sort demonstrate as opposed to level of them. It is accepted that the development of yield relies on upon the physical to human capital proportion where human capital is most certainly not just measured by instruction additionally by wellbeing or sustenance status. Accordingly, human capital is characterized in this study with individual instruction level and dietary status. In the event that there is an irregularity impact in
  • 6. the middle of physical and human capital, the awkwardness impact that is a symmetric condition on the physical to human capital proportion will be fundamentally beneath or over its enduring state esteem. The uneven unevenness impact is exhibited by a kilter U-molded reliance or if the every capita yield development depends just as decidedly or just as adversely on the physical to human degree. They generally state prove that development depends absolutely on the physical to human capital degree. Islam (1995) discovers negative human capital coefficients. This negative sign of human capital coefficients is considered by us to be an evidence for the importance of physical to human capital degree in development study. They draw thoughtfulness regarding the complementarities between human capital and physical capital. The complementarities between human capital and physical capital are the regular of the generation technique since gear needs qualified laborers to oversee them and qualified mechanics to settle them. Also, even advanced agrarian creation obliges a generally educated horticulture workforce where specialists who can understand directions on a compost pack, get it data contained in manual conveyed by augmentation specialists and get it the substance of a repair manual for agrarian supplies and up-to-the-moment administrations need individuals who can make basic estimations quickly and exactly. On the off chance that nations concentrate on physical capital while overlooking their human capital, they will before long get to be cognizant that the comes back to physical capital are more terrible than they need to be then they will have poorer yield. They likewise uncovered that presenting unrivaled strategies for creation, better approaches for doing things and presenting more compound and entangled items are simpler said than done on the off chance that purchasers, laborers and buyers have unacceptable preparing and instruction to empower them to comprehend the new engineering. Data: We have utilized information for 1990 and 2000 for 36
  • 7. nations where 1980' every capita GDP level information is gotten for beginning starting salary level. The physical cash flow to education*worker exertion level information is computed as electric power utilization (kwh) to Education (E) information times the specialist exertion record (e) (EL/E*e). EL/E*e electric force utilization (kwh) demonstrated as (EL) stands for physical capital intermediary and Education (E) information is the aggregate instructed individuals who took normal Years of School from instructive accomplishment of the matured 15. Every capita dietary vitality supply (DES) is taken from Fao1 to compute the specialist exertion level (e). Downright populace variables are taken from the World Improvement Indicators to figure populace development rates. Gross domestic product every capita and all out populaces and EL/E*e electric force utilization (kwh) are from World Bank's World Development Indicators2. Instruction (E) information originates from the Barro- Lee information set. Change in physical cashflow to instruction information is figured as change in EL/E*e electric force utilization (kwh) to Education (E) information and the laborer exertion record (e) (EL/E*e). Since we plan to utilize physical to human capital degree as the integral communication in our increasing Solow model, we ought to draw the illustrations of the normal every capita salary development and the EL/E*e. The reliance on the every capita salary development on K/H proportion in figure 1 is not U molded. One-part endogenous development models expect a U-formed reliance of generation development on the backwards proportion of physical to human capital. Greenwood (1997) says that financial development hypothesis equivocally infers the lopsidedness impact. This awkwardness impact is portrayed as the proportion of physical to human capital or human to physical capital. As we see from the figure 1, aggregate and sub-examples demonstrates no U-formed. In any case, it is tricky to close there is a positive relationship between normal every capita pay development and EL/E*e with the exception of high-pay sub example and entire specimen. The normal of
  • 8. (EL/E*e) is the 650066.1 and the standard deviation parallels 617684.1. The normal of normal every capita wage development is 0.202358 furthermore the standard deviation levels with 0.1988373. We have likewise report for the sub test. For the high pay level nations (as indicated by World Bank 2002 characterization where mid and low pay level nations are accounted for in the same bunch), the normal of normal every capita pay development is 0.204 and the standard deviation rises to 0.124, the normal of (EL/E*e) is the 1081703 and the standard deviation rises to 656372.1. For the low pay level nations, the normal of normal every capita wage development is 0. 20 and the standard deviation levels with 0.25, the normal of (EL/E*e) is the 284834.5 and the standard deviation levels with 226639.3. Both of these measurements are higher in the high- salary nations. The relationship of the normal of (EL/E*e) and normal every capita salary development for the entire specimen is -0.0745 (0.5341). It is -0.2106 (0.2394) for high income level and it is -0.0660 (0.6899) for the low-wage level. Financial development is regularly measured as the change in every capita Gross Domestic Item (GDP). Maintained long haul financial development at a positive rate is a genuinely later wonder in mankind's history, the vast majority of it having happened in the most recent 200 years. As indicated by Maddison's (2001) evaluations, every capita GDP on the planet economy was no higher in the year 1000 than in the year 1, and just 53% higher in 1820 than in 1000, suggesting a normal yearly development rate of stand out nineteenth of one percent over the recent 820 year period. Sooner or later around 1820, the world development rate began to climb, averaging a little more than one 50% of one percent every year from 1820 to 1870, and topping amid what Maddison calls the "brilliant age", the period from 1950 to 1973, when it found the middle value of 2.93% every year. By 2000, world every capita GDP had climbed to more than 8 ½ times its 1820 quality. Development has been uneven crosswise over time as well
  • 9. as crosswise over nations. Since 1820, living guidelines in Western Europe and its branches in North America and the Antipodes have dashed in front of whatever remains of the world, except for Japan, in what is frequently alluded to as the "Extraordinary Divergence". The corresponding crevice in every capita GDP between the wealthiest gathering of nations and the poorest gathering (as ordered by Maddison) developed from 3 in 1820 to 19 in 1998. Pritchett (1997) recounts a comparable story, assessing that the relative crevice between the wealthiest and poorest nations developed more than five-fold from 1870 to 1990. Conclusion: We have proposed that the worldwide contrasts in pay per capita are best comprehended utilizing an enlarged Solow development model where physical to human capita degree is utilized rather their level underway capacity. In our model, yield is delivered from physical to human capital proportion what's more work, and that yield is utilized for speculation as a part of physical to human capital degree and utilization. The key object of the paper is to explore how well physical to human capital degree fits in the experimental development consider other than the merging issue. Despite the fact that not the relationship help the positive relationship between normal every capita pay development and EL/E*e, there is a critical positive relationship between the normal every capita salary development and changing in EL/E*e. This study gives confirm that the communication between (K/H) and monetary development has a tendency to be sure in the example of 36 nations for the years 1990 and 2000. All the more by and large, our result demonstrates that Solow model predictable with the worldwide proof regardless of the fact that we utilize (K/H). Hence, our increasing Solow model says that the distinctions in sparing (evolving in (EL/E*e)) and populace and persistence level development should clarify crosscountry contrasts in every capita wage. The union rate is higher than 2% which is more noteworthy than general discoveries. The used information may
  • 10. be steady with the two-segment models of endogenous development with expansive modification costs for moving human capital and models of mechanical dispersion. Exploring the straight relationship between the physical to human capital proportion and the yield development appears to fit well, which give just circuitous affirmation for the unevenness impact. Work Cited Evans, Paul. “Using Cross-Country Variances to Evaluate Growth Theories.” Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 20 (June-July 1996): 1027-49. Frankel, Marvin. “The Production Function in Allocation and Growth: A Synthesis.” American Economic Review 52 (1962): 995-1022. Greenwood, Jeremy, and Mehmet Yorukoglu. “1974.” Carnegie-
  • 11. Rochester ConferenceSeries on Public Policy 46 (June 1997): 49-95. Maddison, Angus. The World Economy: A Millennial Perspective. Development Centre Studies. Paris: OECD, 2001. micecoo.docx I'm a postgraduate student in UK I have A 1500 essay I need your help please Assessment: In a popular paper published in 1992 by the Quarterly Journal of Economics (QJE), Gregory Mankiw, David Romer and David Weil (MRW) conclude that: "international differences in income per capita are best understood using an [economic] growth model [where] output is produced from physical capital, human capital, and labor, and is used for investment in physical capital, investment in human capital, and consumption." (Mankiw et al. 1992 , p. 432) Using the Eviews/GRETL dataset attached, carefully explain the empirical evidence MRW provide in support in of their thesis. In the light of this econometric analysis, do you share the authors’ conclusion above?
  • 12. Answer in about 1500 words (all included). Additional information Deadline: Please submit an electronic copy of your essay on Study Space Weight: 50% of portfolio assessment, 22.5% of total marks. References [MRW] Mankiw, N.G., Romer, D., Weil, D.N., (1992). A Contribution to the Empirics of Economic Growth. The Quarterly Journal of Economics 107, 407–437. doi:10.2307/2118477 <Available at: http://qje.oxfordjournals.org/content/107/2/407.abstract > I can provide you the reference and all data you need to do the essay with . You can use one of them (E-views or Gretl) it's you choice you can find all data on Mankiw et al. (1992)'s Appendix All data Here with the required reading material p.434-436 page434.pdf A Contribution to the Empirics of Economic Growth Author(s): N. Gregory Mankiw, David Romer and David N. Weil Source: The Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 107, No. 2 (May, 1992), pp. 407-437 Published by: Oxford University Press Stable URL: http://www.jstor.org/stable/2118477 . Accessed: 21/10/2014 08:12
  • 13. Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available at . http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp . JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide range of content in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and facilitate new forms of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact [email protected] . Oxford University Press is collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend access to The Quarterly Journal of Economics. http://www.jstor.org This content downloaded from 141.241.43.86 on Tue, 21 Oct 2014 08:12:36 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions http://www.jstor.org/action/showPublisher?publisherCode=oup http://www.jstor.org/stable/2118477?origin=JSTOR-pdf http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp A CONTRIBUTION TO THE EMPIRICS OF ECONOMIC GROWTH* N. GREGORY MANKIW
  • 14. DAVID ROMER DAVID N. WEIL This paper examines whether the Solow growth model is consistent with the international variation in the standard of living. It shows that an augmented Solow model that includes accumulation of human as well as physical capital provides an excellent description of the cross-country data. The paper also examines the implications of the Solow model for convergence in standards of living, that is, for whether poor countries tend to grow faster than rich countries. The evidence indicates that, holding population growth and capital accumulation constant, countries converge at about the rate the augmented Solow model predicts. INTRODUCTION This paper takes Robert Solow seriously. In his classic 1956 article Solow proposed that we begin the study of economic growth by assuming a standard neoclassical production function with decreasing returns to capital. Taking the rates of saving and population growth as exogenous, he showed that these two vari- ables determine the steady-state level of income per capita. Be- cause saving and population growth rates vary across countries, different countries reach different steady states. Solow's model gives simple testable predictions about how these variables influ- ence the steady-state level of income. The higher the rate of saving,
  • 15. the richer the country. The higher the rate of population growth, the poorer the country. This paper argues that the predictions of the Solow model are, to a first approximation, consistent with the evidence. Examining recently available data for a large set of countries, we find that saving and population growth affect income in the directions that Solow predicted. Moreover, more than half of the cross-country variation in income per capita can be explained by these two variables alone. Yet all is not right for the Solow model. Although the model correctly predicts the directions of the effects of saving and *We are grateful to Karen Dynan for research assistance, to Laurence Ball, Olivier Blanchard, Anne Case, Lawrence Katz, Robert King, Paul Romer, Xavier Sala-i-Martin, Amy Salsbury, Robert Solow, Lawrence Summers, Peter Temin, and the referees for helpful comments, and to the National Science Foundation for financial support. ? 1992 by the President and Fellows of Harvard College and the Massachusetts Institute of Technology. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, May 1992 This content downloaded from 141.241.43.86 on Tue, 21 Oct 2014 08:12:36 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp
  • 16. 408 QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS population growth, it does not correctly predict the magnitudes. In the data the effects of saving and population growth on income are too large. To understand the relation between saving, population growth, and income, one must go beyond the textbook Solow model. We therefore augment the Solow model by including accumu- lation of human as well as physical capital. The exclusion of human capital from the textbook Solow model can potentially explain why the estimated influences of saving and population growth appear too large, for two reasons. First, for any given rate of human- capital accumulation, higher saving or lower population growth leads to a higher level of income and thus a higher level of human capital; hence, accumulation of physical capital and population growth have greater impacts on income when accumulation of human capital is taken into account. Second, human-capital accu- mulation may be correlated with saving rates and population growth rates; this would imply that omitting human-capital accu- mulation biases the estimated coefficients on saving and population growth. To test the augmented Solow model, we include a proxy for human-capital accumulation as an additional explanatory variable
  • 17. in our cross-country regressions. We find that accumulation of human capital is in fact correlated with saving and population growth. Including human-capital accumulation lowers the esti- mated effects of saving and population growth to roughly the values predicted by the augmented Solow model. Moreover, the augmented model accounts for about 80 percent of the cross- country variation in income. Given the inevitable imperfections in this sort of cross-country data, we consider the fit of this simple model to be remarkable. It appears that the augmented Solow model provides an almost complete explanation of why some countries are rich and other countries are poor. After developing and testing the augmented Solow model, we examine an issue that has received much attention in recent years: the failure of countries to converge in per capita income. We argue that one should not expect convergence. Rather, the Solow model predicts that countries generally reach different steady states. We examine empirically the set of countries for which nonconvergence has been widely documented in past work. We find that once differences in saving and population growth rates are accounted for, there is convergence at roughly the rate that the model predicts. This content downloaded from 141.241.43.86 on Tue, 21 Oct 2014 08:12:36 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp
  • 18. THE EMPIRICS OF ECONOMIC GROWTH 409 Finally, we discuss the predictions of the Solow model for international variation in rates of return and for capital move- ments. The model predicts that poor countries should tend to have higher rates of return to physical and human capital. We discuss various evidence that one might use to evaluate this prediction. In contrast to many recent authors, we interpret the available evidence on rates of return as generally consistent with the Solow model. Overall, the findings reported in this paper cast doubt on the recent trend among economists to dismiss the Solow growth model in favor of endogenous-growth models that assume constant or increasing returns to scale in capital. One can explain much of the cross-country variation in income while maintaining the assump- tion of decreasing returns. This conclusion does not imply, how- ever, that the Solow model is a complete theory of growth: one would like also to understand the determinants of saving, popula- tion growth, and worldwide technological change, all of which the Solow model treats as exogenous. Nor does it imply that endogenous- growth models are not important, for they may provide the right explanation of worldwide technological change. Our conclusion does imply, however, that the Solow model gives the right answers to the questions it is designed to address.
  • 19. I. THE TEXTBOOK SOLOW MODEL We begin by briefly reviewing the Solow growth model. We focus on the model's implications for cross-country data. A. The Model Solow's model takes the rates of saving, population growth, and technological progress as exogenous. There are two inputs, capital and labor, which are paid their marginal products. We assume a Cobb-Douglas production function, so production at time t is given by (1) Y(t) = K(t)a(A(t)L(t))l- 0 < a. < 1. The notation is standard: Y is output, K capital, L labor, and A the level of technology. L and A are assumed to grow exogenously at rates n and g: (2) L (t) = L ()ent (3) A (t) = A (r)ent. The number of effective units of labor, A (t)L (t), grows at rate n + g. This content downloaded from 141.241.43.86 on Tue, 21 Oct 2014 08:12:36 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp
  • 20. 410 QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS The model assumes that a constant fraction of output, s, is invested. Defining k as the stock of capital per effective unit of labor, k = KIAL, and y as the level of output per effective unit of labor, y = Y/AL, the evolution of k is governed by (4) k(t) = sy(t) - (n + g + 8)k (t) = sk(t)0 - (n + g + 8)k(t), where 8 is the rate of depreciation. Equation (4) implies that k converges to a steady-state value k* defined by sk *a = (n + g + 8)k *, or (5) k* = [s/(n + g + 5)]1I(1-a) The steady-state capital-labor ratio is related positively to the rate of saving and negatively to the rate of population growth. The central predictions of the Solow model concern the impact of saving and population growth on real income. Substituting (5) into the production function and taking logs, we find that steady- state income per capita is (6)tl [Ot]ln()gt (6) In = In A (0) + gt + 1 In(s) - 1 ln(n + g + 8). Because the model assumes that factors are paid their marginal products, it predicts not only the signs but also the magnitudes of
  • 21. the coefficients on saving and population growth. Specifically, because capital's share in income (a) is roughly one third, the model implies an elasticity of income per capita with respect to the saving rate of approximately 0.5 and an elasticity with respect to n + g + 8 of approximately -0.5. B. Specification The natural question to consider is whether the data support the Solow model's predictions concerning the determinants of standards of living. In other words, we want to investigate whether real income is higher in countries with higher saving rates and lower in countries with higher values of n + g + 5. We assume that g and 8 are constant across countries. g reflects primarily the advancement of knowledge, which is not country-specific. And there is neither any strong reason to expect depreciation rates to vary greatly across countries, nor are there any data that would allow us to estimate country-specific deprecia- tion rates. In contrast, the A(0) term reflects not just technology This content downloaded from 141.241.43.86 on Tue, 21 Oct 2014 08:12:36 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp THE EMPIRICS OF ECONOMIC GROWTH 411 but resource endowments, climate, institutions, and so on; it
  • 22. may therefore differ across countries. We assume that lnA(O) = a + E, where a is a constant and E is a country-specific shock. Thus, log income per capita at a given time-time 0 for simplicity-is (7) In a+ In(s)- In(n+g+8)+E. Equation (7) is our basic empirical specification in this section. We assume that the rates of saving and population growth are independent of country-specific factors shifting the production function. That is, we assume that s and n are independent of e. This assumption implies that we can estimate equation (7) with ordi- nary least squares (OLS).1 There are three reasons for making this assumption of indepen- dence. First, this assumption is made not only in the Solow model, but also in many standard models of economic growth. In any model in which saving and population growth are endogenous but preferences are isoelastic, s and n are unaffected by E. In other words, under isoelastic utility, permanent differences in the level of technology do not affect saving rates or population growth rates. Second, much recent theoretical work on growth has been motivated by informal examinations of the relationships between saving, population growth, and income. Many economists have
  • 23. asserted that the Solow model cannot account for the international differences in income, and this alleged failure of the Solow model has stimulated work on endogenous-growth theory. For example, Romer [1987, 1989a] suggests that saving has too large an influence on growth and takes this to be evidence for positive externalities from capital accumulation. Similarly, Lucas [1988] asserts that variation in population growth cannot account for any substantial variation in real incomes along the lines predicted by the Solow model. By maintaining the identifying assumption that s and n are independent of E, we are able to determine whether systematic examination of the data confirms these informal judg- ments. 1. If s and n are endogenous and influenced by the level of income, then estimates of equation (7) using ordinary least squares are potentially inconsistent. In this case, to obtain consistent estimates, one needs to find instrumental variables that are correlated with s and n, but uncorrelated with the country-specific shift in the production function e. Finding such instrumental variables is a formidable task, however. This content downloaded from 141.241.43.86 on Tue, 21 Oct 2014 08:12:36 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
  • 24. http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp 412 QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS Third, because the model predicts not just the signs but also the magnitudes of the coefficients on saving and population growth, we can gauge whether there are important biases in the estimates obtained with OLS. As described above, data on factor shares imply that, if the model is correct, the elasticities of Y/L with respect to s and n + g + 8 are approximately 0.5 and -0.5. If OLS yields coefficients that are substantially different from these values, then we can reject the joint hypothesis that the Solow model and our identifying assumption are correct. Another way to evaluate the Solow model would be to impose on equation (7) a value of ao derived from data on factor shares and then to ask how much of the cross-country variation in income the model can account for. That is, using an approach analogous to "growth accounting," we could compute the fraction of the vari- ance in living standards that is explained by the mechanism identified by the Solow model.2 In practice, because we do not have exact estimates of factor shares, we do not emphasize this growth- accounting approach. Rather, we estimate equation (7) by OLS and examine the plausibility of the implied factor shares. The fit of this regression shows the result of a growth-accounting exercise per- formed with the estimated value of a. If the estimated a differs
  • 25. from the value obtained a priori from factor shares, we can compare the fit of the estimated regression with the fit obtained by imposing the a priori value. C. Data and Samples The data are from the Real National Accounts recently constructed by Summers and Heston [1988]. The data set includes real income, government and private consumption, investment, and population for almost all of the world other than the centrally planned economies. The data are annual and cover the period 1960-1985. We measure n as the average rate of growth of the working-age population, where working age is defined as 15 to 64.3 We measure s as the average share of real investment (including 2. In standard growth accounting, factor shares are used to decompose growth over time in a single country into a part explained by growth in factor inputs and an unexplained part-the Solow residual-which is usually attributed to technological change. In this cross-country analogue, factor shares are used to decompose variation in income across countries into a part explained by variation in saving and population growth rates and an unexplained part, which could be attributed to international differences in the level of technology. 3. Data on the fraction of the population of working age are from the World Bank's World Tables and the 1988 World Development Report.
  • 26. This content downloaded from 141.241.43.86 on Tue, 21 Oct 2014 08:12:36 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp THE EMPIRICS OF ECONOMIC GROWTH 413 government investment) in real GDP, and Y/L as real GDP in 1985 divided by the working-age population in that year. We consider three samples of countries. The most comprehen- sive consists of all countries for which data are available other than those for which oil production is the dominant industry.4 This sample consists of 98 countries. We exclude the oil producers because the bulk of recorded GDP for these countries represents the extraction of existing resources, not value added; one should not expect standard growth models to account for measured GDP in these countries.5 Our second sample excludes countries whose data receive a grade of "D" from Summers and Heston or whose populations in 1960 were less than one million. Summers and Heston use the "D" grade to identify countries whose real income figures are based on extremely little primary data; measurement error is likely to be a greater problem for these countries. We omit the small countries because the determination of their real income may be dominated
  • 27. by idiosyncratic factors. This sample consists of 75 countries. The third sample consists of the 22 OECD countries with populations greater than one million. This sample has the advan- tages that the data appear to be uniformly of high quality and that the variation in omitted country-specific factors is likely to be small. But it has the disadvantages that it is small in size and that it discards much of the variation in the variables of interest. See the Appendix for the countries in each of the samples and the data. D. Results We estimate equation (7) both with and without imposing the constraint that the coefficients on ln(s) and ln(n + g + 8) are equal in magnitude and opposite in sign. We assume that g + 8 is 0.05; reasonable changes in this assumption have little effect on the estimates.6 Table I reports the results. 4. For purposes of comparability, we restrict the sample to countries that have not only the data used in this section, but also the data on human capital described in Section II. 5. The countries that are excluded on this basis are Bahrain, Gabon, Iran, Iraq, Kuwait, Oman, Saudi Arabia, and the United Arab Emirates. In addition, Lesotho is excluded because the sum of private and government
  • 28. consumption far exceeds GDP in every year of the sample, indicating that labor income from abroad constitutes an extremely large fraction of GNP. 6. We chose this value of g + 8 to match the available data. In U. S. data the capital consumption allowance is about 10 percent of GNP, and the capital-output ratio is about three, which implies that 8 is about 0.03; Romer [1989a, p. 60] presents a calculation for a broader sample of countries and concludes that 8 is This content downloaded from 141.241.43.86 on Tue, 21 Oct 2014 08:12:36 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp 414 QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS TABLE I ESTIMATION OF THE TEXTBOOK SOLOW MODEL Dependent variable: log GDP per working-age person in 1985 Sample: Non-oil Intermediate OECD Observations: 98 75 22 CONSTANT 5.48 5.36 7.97 (1.59) (1.55) (2.48) ln(I/GDP) 1.42 1.31 0.50 (0.14) (0.17) (0.43)
  • 29. ln(n + g + 8) -1.97 -2.01 -0.76 (0.56) (0.53) (0.84) H2 0.59 0.59 0.01 s.e.e. 0.69 0.61 0.38 Restricted regression: CONSTANT 6.87 7.10 8.62 (0.12) (0.15) (0.53) ln(I/GDP) - ln(n + g + 8) 1.48 1.43 0.56 (0.12) (0.14) (0.36) 1?2 0.59 0.59 0.06 s.e.e. 0.69 0.61 0.37 Test of restriction: p-value 0.38 0.26 0.79 Implied a 0.60 0.59 0.36 (0.02) (0.02) (0.15) Note. Standard errors are in parentheses. The investment and population growth rates are averages for the period 1960-1985. (g + 8) is assumed to be 0.05. Three aspects of the results support the Solow model. First, the coefficients on saving and population growth have the predicted signs and, for two of the three samples, are highly significant. Second, the restriction that the coefficients on ln(s) and ln(n + g + 8) are equal in magnitude and opposite in sign is not rejected in any of the samples. Third, and perhaps most important, differences in saving and population growth account for a large fraction of the cross-country variation in income per capita. In the
  • 30. regression for the intermediate sample, for example, the adjusted R2 is 0.59. In contrast to the common claim that the Solow model "explains" cross-country variation in labor productivity largely by appealing to variations in technologies, the two readily observable about 0.03 or 0.04. In addition, growth in income per capita has averaged 1.7 percent per year in the United States and 2.2 percent per year in our intermediate sample; this suggests that g is about 0.02. This content downloaded from 141.241.43.86 on Tue, 21 Oct 2014 08:12:36 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp THE EMPIRICS OF ECONOMIC GROWTH 415 variables on which the Solow model focuses in fact account for most of the variation in income per capita. Nonetheless, the model is not completely successful. In par- ticular, the estimated impacts of saving and labor force growth are much larger than the model predicts. The value of a. implied by the coefficients should equal capital's share in income, which is roughly one third. The estimates, however, imply an a that is much higher.
  • 31. For example, the a implied by the coefficient in the constrained regression for the intermediate sample is 0.59 (with a standard error of 0.02). Thus, the data strongly contradict the prediction that a = 1/3. Because the estimates imply such a high capital share, it is inappropriate to conclude that the Solow model is successful just because the regressions in Table I can explain a high fraction of the variation in income. For the intermediate sample, for instance, when we employ the "growth-accounting" approach described above and constrain the coefficients to be consistent with an a of one third, the adjusted R2 falls from 0.59 to 0.28. Although the excellent fit of the simple regressions in Table I is promising for the theory of growth in general-it implies that theories based on easily observable variables may be able to account for most of the cross-country variation in real income it is not supportive of the textbook Solow model in particular. II. ADDING HUMAN-CAPITAL ACCUMULATION TO THE SOLOW MODEL Economists have long stressed the importance of human capital to the process of growth. One might expect that ignoring human capital would lead to incorrect conclusions: Kendrick [1976] estimates that over half of the total U. S. capital stock in 1969 was human capital. In this section we explore the effect of adding human-capital accumulation to the Solow growth model. Including human capital can potentially alter either the theoretical modeling or the empirical analysis of economic growth.
  • 32. At the theoretical level, properly accounting for human capital may change one's view of the nature of the growth process. Lucas [1988], for example, assumes that although there are decreasing returns to physical-capital accumulation when human capital is held constant, the returns to all reproducible capital (human plus physical) are constant. We discuss this possibility in Section III. At the empirical level, the existence of human capital can alter the analysis of cross-country differences; in the regressions in This content downloaded from 141.241.43.86 on Tue, 21 Oct 2014 08:12:36 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp 416 QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS Table I human capital is an omitted variable. It is this empirical problem that we pursue in this section. We first expand the Solow model of Section I to include human capital. We show how leaving out human capital affects the coefficients on physical capital investment and population growth. We then run regressions analogous to those in Table I to see whether proxies for human capital can resolve the anomalies found in the first section.7 A. The Model Let the production function be
  • 33. (8) Y(t) = K(t)H(t)P(A(t)L(t))1-a-, where H is the stock of human capital, and all other variables are defined as before. Let Sk be the fraction of income invested in physical capital and Sh the fraction invested in human capital. The evolution of the economy is determined by (9a) k(t) = sky(t) - (n + g + 8)k(t), (9b) h(t) = Shy(t) - (n + g + 8)h(t), where y = Y/AL, k = K/AL, and h = H/AL are quantities per effective unit of labor. We are assuming that the same production function applies to human capital, physical capital, and consump- tion. In other words, one unit of consumption can be transformed costlessly into either one unit of physical capital or one unit of human capital. In addition, we are assuming that human capital depreciates at the same rate as physical capital. Lucas [1988] models the production function for human capital as fundamen- tally different from that for other goods. We believe that, at least for an initial examination, it is natural to assume that the two types of production functions are similar. We assume that a + ,B < 1, which implies that there are decreasing returns to all capital. (If a + ,B = 1, then there are constant returns to scale in the reproducible factors. In this case, 7. Previous authors have provided evidence of the importance of human capital for growth in income. Azariadis and Drazen [1990] find that no
  • 34. country was able to grow quickly during the postwar period without a highly literate labor force. They interpret this as evidence that there is a threshold externality associated with human capital accumulation. Similarly, Rauch [1988] finds that among countries that had achieved 95 percent adult literacy in 1960, there was a strong tendency for income per capita to converge over the period 1950-1985. Romer [1989b] finds that literacy in 1960 helps explain subsequent investment and that, if one corrects for measurement error, literacy has no impact on growth beyond its effect on investment. There is also older work stressing the role of human capital in development; for example, see Krueger [1968] and Easterlin [1981]. This content downloaded from 141.241.43.86 on Tue, 21 Oct 2014 08:12:36 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp THE EMPIRICS OF ECONOMIC GROWTH 417 there is no steady state for this model. We discuss this possibility in Section III.) Equations (9a) and (9b) imply that the economy converges to a steady state defined by n + g + (10)
  • 35. (* a k -S a 1/(1-a-) , n +g+ / Substituting (10) into the production function and taking logs gives an equation for income per capita similar to equation (6) above: (1 1) In [L(t)| In A(O) + gt - + (I ln(n + g + a Y (t)]_ + Iln(Sk) + In(Sh) This equation shows how income per capita depends on population growth and accumulation of physical and human capital. Like the textbook Solow model, the augmented model predicts coefficients in equation (11) that are functions of the factor shares. As before, a is physical capital's share of income, so we expect a value of a of about one third. Gauging a reasonable value of P, human capital's share, is more difficult. In the United States the minimum wage-roughly the return to labor without human capital-has averaged about 30 to 50 percent of the average wage in manufacturing. This fact suggests that 50 to 70 percent of total labor income represents the return to human capital, or that ,B is between one third and one half. Equation (11) makes two predictions about the regressions
  • 36. run in Section I, in which human capital was ignored. First, even if In (Sh) is independent of the other right-hand side variables, the coefficient on ln(sk) is greater than a/(1 - a). For example, if a = P = 1/3, then the coefficient on ln(sk) would be 1. Because higher saving leads to higher income, it leads to a higher steady-state level of human capital, even if the percentage of income devoted to human-capital accumulation is unchanged. Hence, the presence of human-capital accumulation increases the impact of physical- capital accumulation on income. Second, the coefficient on ln(n + g + 8) is larger in absolute This content downloaded from 141.241.43.86 on Tue, 21 Oct 2014 08:12:36 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp 418 QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS value than the coefficient on ln(sk). If a =P = 1/3, for example, the coefficient on ln(n + g + 8) would be -2. In this model high population growth lowers income per capita because the amounts of both physical and human capital must be spread more thinly over the population. There is an alternative way to express the role of human capital in determining income in this model. Combining (11)
  • 37. with the equation for the steady-state level of human capital given in (10) yields an equation for income as a function of the rate of investment in physical capital, the rate of population growth, and the level of human capital: (12) In [L(t) = InA(O) + gt + 1 _ ln(sk) aL Wi 1 -a n(n + g + 8) + - ln(h*). Equation (12) is almost identical to equation (6) in Section I. In that model the level of human capital is a component of the error term. Because the saving and population growth rates influence h *, one should expect human capital to be positively correlated with the saving rate and negatively correlated with population growth. Therefore, omitting the human-capital term biases the coefficients on saving and population growth. The model with human capital suggests two possible ways to modify our previous regressions. One way is to estimate the augmented model's reduced form, that is, equation (11), in which the rate of human-capital accumulation ln(sh) is added to the right-hand side. The second way is to estimate equation (12), in which the level of human capital In (h *) is added to the right- hand side. Notice that these alternative regressions predict different coefficients on the saving and population growth terms. When testing the augmented Solow model, a primary question is whether the available data on human capital correspond more closely to the rate of accumulation (Sh) or to the level of human capital (h).
  • 38. B. Data To implement the model, we restrict our focus to human- capital investment in the form of education-thus ignoring invest- ment in health, among other things. Despite this narrowed focus, measurement of human capital presents great practical difficulties. Most important, a large part of investment in education takes the This content downloaded from 141.241.43.86 on Tue, 21 Oct 2014 08:12:36 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp THE EMPIRICS OF ECONOMIC GROWTH 419 form of forgone labor earnings on the part of students.8 This problem is difficult to overcome because forgone earnings vary with the level of human-capital investment: a worker with little human capital forgoes a low wage in order to accumulate more human capital, whereas a worker with much human capital forgoes a higher wage. In addition, explicit spending on education takes place at all levels of government as well as by the family, which makes spending on education hard to measure. Finally, not all spending on education is intended to yield productive human capital:
  • 39. philosophy, religion, and literature, for example, although serving in part to train the mind, might also be a form of consumption.9 We use a proxy for the rate of human-capital accumulation (Sh) that measures approximately the percentage of the working-age population that is in secondary school. We begin with data on the fraction of the eligible population (aged 12 to 17) enrolled in secondary school, which we obtained from the UNESCO yearbook. We then multiply this enrollment rate by the fraction of the working-age population that is of school age (aged 15 to 19). This variable, which we call SCHOOL, is clearly imperfect: the age ranges in the two data series are not exactly the same, the variable does not include the input of teachers, and it completely ignores primary and higher education. Yet if SCHOOL is proportional to Sh, then we can use it to estimate equation (11); the factor of proportionality will affect only the constant term.10 This measure indicates that investment in physical capital and population growth may be proxying for human-capital accumula- tion in the regressions in Table I. The correlation between SCHOOL 8. Kendrick [19761 calculates that for the United States in 1969 total gross investment in education and training was $192.3 billion, of which $92.3 billion took the form of imputed compensation to students (tables A-1 and B-2).
  • 40. 9. An additional problem with implementing the augmented model is that "output" in the model is not the same as that measured in the national income accounts. Much of the expenditure on human capital is forgone wages, and these forgone wages should be included in Y. Yet measured GDP fails to include this component of investment spending. Back-of-the-envelope calculations suggest that this problem is not quantita- tively important, however. If human capital accumulation is completely unmea- sured, then measured GDP is (1 - Sh)y. One can show that this measurement problem does not affect the elasticity of GDP with respect to physical investment or population growth. The elasticity of measured GDP with respect to human capital accumulation is reduced by Shl(l - Sh) compared with the elasticity of true GDP with respect to human capital accumulation. Because the fraction of a nation's resources devoted to human capital accumulation is small, this effect is small. For example, if a = P = 1/3 and Sh = 0.1, then the elasticity will be 0.9 rather than 1.0. 10. Even under the weaker assumption that ln(sh) is linear in In (SCHOOL), we can use the estimated coefficients on ln(sk) and In (n + g + 5) to infer values of a and P; in this case, the estimated coefficient on In (SCHOOL) will not have an interpretation.
  • 41. This content downloaded from 141.241.43.86 on Tue, 21 Oct 2014 08:12:36 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp 420 QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS and I/GDP is 0.59 for the intermediate sample, and the correlation between SCHOOL and the population growth rate is -0.38. Thus, including human-capital accumulation could alter substantially the estimated impact of physical-capital accumulation and popula- tion growth on income per capita. C. Results Table II presents regressions of the log of income per capita on the log of the investment rate, the log of n + g + 8, and the log of the percentage of the population in secondary school. The human- capital measure enters significantly in all three samples. It also TABLE II ESTIMATION OF THE AUGMENTED SOLOW MODEL Dependent variable: log GDP per working-age person in 1985 Sample: Non-oil Intermediate OECD Observations: 98 75 22 CONSTANT 6.89 7.81 8.63
  • 42. (1.17) (1.19) (2.19) ln(I/GDP) 0.69 0.70 0.28 (0.13) (0.15) (0.39) ln(n + g + 5) -1.73 -1.50 -1.07 (0.41) (0.40) (0.75) ln(SCHOOL) 0.66 0.73 0.76 (0.07) (0.10) (0.29) R2 0.78 0.77 0.24 s.e.e. 0.51 0.45 0.33 Restricted regression: CONSTANT 7.86 7.97 8.71 (0.14) (0.15) (0.47) ln(I/GDP) - ln(n + g + 5) 0.73 0.71 0.29 (0.12) (0.14) (0.33) ln(SCHOOL) - ln(n + g + 5) 0.67 0.74 0.76 (0.07) (0.09) (0.28) R2 0.78 0.77 0.28 s.e.e. 0.51 0.45 0.32 Test of restriction: p-value 0.41 0.89 0.97 Implied a 0.31 0.29 0.14 (0.04) (0.05) (0.15) Implied , 0.28 0.30 0.37 (0.03) (0.04) (0.12) Note. Standard errors are in parentheses. The investment and
  • 43. population growth rates are averages for the period 1960-1985. (g + 8) is assumed to be 0.05. SCHOOL is the average percentage of the working-age population in secondary school for the period 1960-1985. This content downloaded from 141.241.43.86 on Tue, 21 Oct 2014 08:12:36 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp THE EMPIRICS OF ECONOMIC GROWTH 421 greatly reduces the size of the coefficient on physical capital investment and improves the fit of the regression compared with Table I. These three variables explain almost 80 percent of the cross-country variation in income per capita in the non-oil and intermediate samples. The results in Table II strongly support the augmented Solow model. Equation (11) shows that the augmented model predicts that the coefficients on In (IIY), In (SCHOOL), and In (n + g + 8) sum to zero. The bottom half of Table II shows that, for all three samples, this restriction is not rejected. The last lines of the table give the values of a and ,B implied by the coefficients in the restricted regression. For non-oil and intermediate samples, a and ,B are about one third and highly significant. The estimates for the OECD alone are less precise. In this sample the coefficients on investment and population growth are not statistically significant;
  • 44. but they are also not significantly different from the estimates obtained in the larger samples.'1 We conclude that adding human capital to the Solow model improves its performance. Allowing for human capital eliminates the worrisome anomalies-the high coefficients on investment and on population growth in our Table I regressions-that arise when the textbook Solow model is confronted with the data. The parameter estimates seem reasonable. And even using an imprecise proxy for human capital, we are able to dispose of a fairly large part of the model's residual variance. III. ENDOGENOUS GROWTH AND CONVERGENCE Over the past few years economists studying growth have turned increasingly to endogenous-growth models. These models are characterized by the assumption of nondecreasing returns to the set of reproducible factors of production. For example, our model with physical and human capital would become an endoge- nous-growth model if a + ,B = 1. Among the implications of this assumption are that countries that save more grow faster indefi- nitely and that countries need not converge in income per capita, even if they have the same preferences and technology. 11. As we described in the previous footnote, under the weaker assumption that ln(sh) is linear in In (SCHOOL), estimates of a and , can be inferred from the coefficients on ln(I/GDP) and ln(n + g + 5) in the unrestricted
  • 45. regression. When we do this, we obtain estimates of a and , little different from those reported in Table II. This content downloaded from 141.241.43.86 on Tue, 21 Oct 2014 08:12:36 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp 422 QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS Advocates of endogenous-growth models present them as alternatives to the Solow model and motivate them by an alleged empirical failure of the Solow model to explain cross-country differences. Barro [1989] presents the argument succinctly: In neoclassical growth models with diminishing returns, such as Solow (1956), Cass (1965) and Koopmans (1965), a country's per capita growth rate tends to be inversely related to its starting level of income per person. Therefore, in the absence of shocks, poor and rich countries would tend to converge in terms of levels of per capita income. However, this convergence hypothesis seems to be inconsistent with the cross-country evidence, which indicates that per capita growth rates are uncorrelated with the starting level of per capita product. Our first goal in this section is to reexamine this evidence on convergence to assess whether it contradicts the Solow model.
  • 46. Our second goal is to generalize our previous results. To implement the Solow model, we have been assuming that countries in 1985 were in their steady states (or, more generally, that the deviations from steady state were random). Yet this assumption is questionable. We therefore examine the predictions of the aug- mented Solow model for behavior out of the steady state. A. Theory The Solow model predicts that countries reach different steady states. In Section II we argued that much of the cross-country differences in income per capita can be traced to differing determi- nants of the steady state in the Solow growth model: accumulation of human and physical capital and population growth. Thus, the Solow model does not predict convergence; it predicts only that income per capita in a given country converges to that country's steady-state value. In other words, the Solow model predicts convergence only after controlling for the determinants of the steady state, a phenomenon that might be called "conditional convergence." In addition, the Solow model makes quantitative predictions about the speed of convergence to steady state. Let y * be the steady-state level of income per effective worker given by equation (11), and let y(t) be the actual value at time t. Approximating around the steady state, the speed of convergence is given by d ln(y(t)) (13) dt = X[ln(y*) -ln(y(t))],
  • 47. where A = (n + g + a) (1-a - This content downloaded from 141.241.43.86 on Tue, 21 Oct 2014 08:12:36 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp THE EMPIRICS OF ECONOMIC GROWTH 423 For example, if a = P = 1/3 and n + g + 8 = 0.06, then the convergence rate (A) would equal 0.02. This implies that the economy moves halfway to steady state in about 35 years. Notice that the textbook Solow model, which excludes human capital, implies much faster convergence. If IB = 0, then X becomes 0.04, and the economy moves halfway to steady state in about seventeen years. The model suggests a natural regression to study the rate of convergence. Equation (13) implies that (14) ln(y(t)) = (1 - e-At) ln(y*) + e-At ln(y(0)), where y(O) is income per effective worker at some initial date. Subtracting In (y(O)) from both sides, (15) ln(y(t)) - ln(y(0)) = (1 - e-t) ln(y*) - (1 - e-At) ln(y(0)). Finally, substituting for y*:
  • 48. (16) ln(y(t)) - ln(y(0)) = (1 - e-t) ln(sk) + (1 - e-t) ln(sh) - (1 - eAxt) l _ _ In(n + g + 8) - (1 - e-t) ln(y(0)). Thus, in the Solow model the growth of income is a function of the determinants of the ultimate steady state and the initial level of income. Endogenous-growth models make predictions very different from the Solow model regarding convergence among countries. In endogenous-growth models there is no steady-state level of income; differences among countries in income per capita can persist indefinitely, even if the countries have the same saving and population growth rates.12 Endogenous-growth models with a 12. Although we do not explore the issue here, endogenous- growth models also make quantitative predictions about the impact of saving on growth. The models are typically characterized by constant returns to reproducible factors of production, namely physical and human capital. Our model of Section II with a + , = 1 and g = 0 provides a simple way of analyzing the predictions of models of endogenous growth. With these modifications to the model of Section II, the production function is Y = AKaH1-a. In this form the model predicts that the ratio of physical to human capital, K/H, will converge to SkiSh, and that K, H, and Y will then all grow at rate
  • 49. A(Sk)a(Sh )'-a. The derivative of this "steady-state" growth rate with respect to Sk is then aA(ShlSk) 1- = atI(KIY). The impact of saving on growth depends on the This content downloaded from 141.241.43.86 on Tue, 21 Oct 2014 08:12:36 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp 424 QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS single sector-those with the "Y = AK" production function- predict no convergence of any sort. That is, these simple endoge- nous-growth models predict a coefficient of zero on y(O) in the regression in (16). As Barro [1989] notes, however, endogenous- growth models with more than one sector may imply convergence if the initial income of a country is correlated with the degree of imbalance among sectors. Before presenting the results on convergence, we should note the differences between regressions based on equation (16) and those we presented earlier. The regressions in Tables I and II are valid only if countries are in their steady states or if deviations from steady state are random. Equation (16) has the advantage of explicitly taking into account out-of-steady-state dynamics. Yet, implementing equation (16) introduces a new problem. If countries have permanent differences in their production functions-that is,
  • 50. different A (O)'s-then these A(O)'s would enter as part of the error term and would be positively correlated with initial income. Hence, variation inA (0) would bias the coefficient on initial income toward zero (and would potentially influence the other coefficients as well). In other words, permanent cross-country differences in the produc- tion function would lead to differences in initial incomes uncorre- lated with subsequent growth rates and, therefore, would bias the results against finding convergence. B. Results We now test the convergence predictions of the Solow model. We report regressions of the change in the log of income per capita over the period 1960 to 1985 on the log of income per capita in 1960, with and without controlling for investment, growth of the working-age population, and school enrollment. In Table III the log of income per capita appears alone on the right-hand side. This table reproduces the results of many previous authors on the failure of incomes to converge [De Long 1988; Romer 1987]. The coefficient on the initial level of income per capita is slightly positive for the non-oil sample and zero for the intermediate sample, and for both regressions the adjusted R2 is exponent on capital in the production function, a, and the
  • 51. capital-output ratio. In models in which endogenous growth arises mainly from externalities from physical capital, a is close to one, and the derivative of the growth rate with respect to Sk is approximately 1 I (KI Y), or about 0.4. In models in which endogenous growth arises largely from human capital accumulation and there are no externalities from physical capital, the derivative would be about 0.31(KIY), or about 0.12. This content downloaded from 141.241.43.86 on Tue, 21 Oct 2014 08:12:36 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp THE EMPIRICS OF ECONOMIC GROWTH 425 TABLE III TESTS FOR UNCONDITIONAL CONVERGENCE Dependent variable: log difference GDP per working-age person 1960-1985 Sample: Non-oil Intermediate OECD Observations: 98 75 22 CONSTANT -0.266 0.587 3.69 (0.380) (0.433) (0.68) ln(Y60) 0.0943 -0.00423 -0.341 (0.0496) (0.05484) (0.079) R2 0.03 -0.01 0.46
  • 52. s.e.e. 0.44 0.41 0.18 Implied X -0.00360 0.00017 0.0167 (0.00219) (0.00218) (0.0023) Note. Standard errors are in parentheses. Y60 is GDP per working-age person in 1960. essentially zero. There is no tendency for poor countries to grow faster on average than rich countries. Table III does show, however, that there is a significant tendency toward convergence in the OECD sample. The coefficient on the initial level of income per capita is significantly negative, and the adjusted R2 of the regression is 0.46. This result confirms the findings of Dowrick and Nguyen [1989], among others. Table IV adds our measures of the rates of investment and population growth to the right-hand side of the regression. In all three samples the coefficient on the initial level of income is now significantly negative; that is, there is strong evidence of conver- gence. Moreover, the inclusion of investment and population growth rates improves substantially the fit of the regression. Table V adds our measure of human capital to the right-hand side of the regression in Table IV. This new variable further lowers the coefficient on the initial level of income, and it again improves the fit of the regression.
  • 53. Figure I presents a graphical demonstration of the effect of adding measures of population growth and accumulation of human and physical capital to the usual "convergence picture," first presented by Romer [1987]. The top panel presents a scatterplot for our intermediate sample of the average annual growth rate of income per capita from 1960 to 1985 against the log of income per capita in 1960. Clearly, there is no evidence that countries that start off poor tend to grow faster. The second panel of the figure This content downloaded from 141.241.43.86 on Tue, 21 Oct 2014 08:12:36 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp 426 QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS TABLE IV TESTS FOR CONDITIONAL CONVERGENCE Dependent variable: log difference GDP per working-age person 1960-1985 Sample: Non-oil Intermediate OECD Observations: 98 75 22 CONSTANT 1.93 2.23 2.19 (0.83) (0.86) (1.17) ln(Y60) -0.141 -0.228 -0.351 (0.052) (0.057) (0.066)
  • 54. ln(I/GDP) 0.647 0.644 0.392 (0.087) (0.104) (0.176) ln(n + g + 8) -0.299 -0.464 -0.753 (0.304) (0.307) (0.341) R72 0.38 0.35 0.62 s.e.e. 0.35 0.33 0.15 Implied X 0.00606 0.0104 0.0173 (0.00182) (0.0019) (0.0019) Note. Standard errors are in parentheses. Y60 is GDP per working-age person in 1960. The investment and population growth rates are averages for the period 1960-1985. (g + 8) is assumed to be 0.05. TABLE V TESTS FOR CONDITIONAL CONVERGENCE Dependent variable: log difference GDP per working-age person 1960-1985 Sample: Non-oil Intermediate OECD Observations: 98 75 22 CONSTANT 3.04 3.69 2.81 (0.83) (0.91) (1.19) ln(Y60) -0.289 -0.366 -0.398 (0.062) (0.067) (0.070) ln(I/GDP) 0.524 0.538 0.335 (0.087) (0.102) (0.174) ln(n + g + 8) -0.505 -0.551 -0.844
  • 55. (0.288) (0.288) (0.334) ln(SCHOOL) 0.233 0.271 0.223 (0.060) (0.081) (0.144) R2 0.46 0.43 0.65 s.e.e. 0.33 0.30 0.15 Implied X 0.0137 0.0182 0.0203 (0.0019) (0.0020) (0.0020) Note. Standard errors are in parentheses. Y60 is GDP per working-age person in 1960. The investment and population growth rates are averages for the period 1960-1985. (g + 8) is assumed to be 0.05. SCHOOL is the average percentage of the working-age population in secondary school for the period 1960-1985. This content downloaded from 141.241.43.86 on Tue, 21 Oct 2014 08:12:36 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp THE EMPIRICS OF ECONOMIC GROWTH 427 A. Unconditional co 6 0 6 0 0 00 (0 ~~~~~0 0 Q) 4 Oo R 0 0O 0 -- ~~00 0 0 2 2 o ? 0 o -~0 0 Oo0 00 ? -2
  • 56. s 5,5 6,5 7,5 8,5 9.5 10.5 Log output per working age adult: 1960 B. Conditional on saving and population growth 6 ~~ ~~0 0 060 0 0 o0c~ 08 W, 4 _CP O? ?? ?0 8 = 2 0 o D 0 o 020 0 5 s,5 6.5 7, 5 8.5 9.5 10,5 Log output per working age adult:1960 C. Conditional on saving, population growth and human capital LO 6 0 0 0~~~~~~ 2 - ? ? O??b 9 lb8 0~~~~~~ ? -2 w 5.5 6.5 7.5 8.5 9.5 10.5 Log output per working age adult: 1960 FIGURE I Unconditional versus Conditional Convergence This content downloaded from 141.241.43.86 on Tue, 21 Oct 2014 08:12:36 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
  • 57. http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp 428 QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS partials out the logs of the investment rate and (n + g + 5) from both the income level and growth rate variables. This figure shows that if countries did not vary in their investment and population growth rates, there would be a strong tendency for poor countries to grow faster than rich ones. The third panel of Figure I partials out our human-capital variable in addition to investment and population growth rates; the tendency toward convergence is now even stronger. The results in Tables IV and V are notable not only for the finding of convergence, but also for the rate at which convergence occurs. The implied values of X, the parameter governing the speed of convergence, are derived from the coefficient on In (Y60). The values in Table IV are much smaller than the textbook Solow model predicts. Yet the estimates in Table V are closer to what the augmented Solow model predicts, for two reasons. First, the augmented model predicts a slower rate of convergence than the model without human capital. Second, the empirical results includ- ing human capital imply a faster rate of convergence than the empirical results without human capital. Hence, once again, the inclusion of human capital can help explain some results that
  • 58. appear anomalous from the vantage point of the textbook Solow model. Table VI presents estimates of equation (16) imposing the restriction that the coefficients on ln(sk), ln(sh), and ln(n + g + 5) sum to zero. We find that this restriction is not rejected and that imposing it has little effect on the coefficients. The last lines in Table VI present the implied values of a and ,. The estimates of a range from 0.38 to 0.48, and the estimates of ,B are 0.23 in all three samples. Compared with the results in Table II, these regressions give a somewhat larger weight to physical capital and a somewhat smaller weight to human capital. In contrast to the results in Tables I through IV, the results for the OECD sample in Tables V and VI are similar to those for the other samples. An interpretation that reconciles the similarity across samples here and the dissimilarity in the earlier specifica- tions is that departures from steady state represent a larger share of cross-country variation in income per capita for the OECD than for the broader samples. If the OECD countries are far from their steady states, then population growth and capital accumulation have not yet had their full impact on standards of living; hence, we obtain lower estimated coefficients and lower R 2's for the OECD in
  • 59. This content downloaded from 141.241.43.86 on Tue, 21 Oct 2014 08:12:36 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp THE EMPIRICS OF ECONOMIC GROWTH 429 TABLE VI TESTS FOR CONDITIONAL CONVERGENCE, RESTRICTED REGRESSION Dependent variable: log difference GDP per working-age person 1960-1985 Sample: Non-oil Intermediate OECD Observations: 98 75 22 CONSTANT 2.46 3.09 3.55 (0.48) (0.53) (0.63) ln(Y60) -0.299 -0.372 -0.402 (0.061) (0.067) (0.069) ln(I/GDP) - ln(n + g + 5) 0.500 0.506 0.396 (0.082) (0.095) (0.152) ln(SCHOOL) - ln(n + g + 5) 0.238 0.266 0.236 (0.060) (0.080) (0.141) R2 0.46 0.44 0.66 s.e.e. 0.33 0.30 0.15 Test of restriction: p-value 0.40 0.42 0.47 ImpliedX 0.0142 0.0186 0.0206
  • 60. (0.0019) (0.0019) (0.0020) Implied (x 0.48 0.44 0.38 (0.07) (0.07) (0.13) Implied 13 0.23 0.23 0.23 (0.05) (0.06) (0.11) Note. Standard errors are in parentheses. Y60 is GDP per working-age person in 1960. The investment and population growth rates are averages for the period 1960-1985. (g + 5) is assumed to be 0.05. SCHOOL is the average percentage of the working-age population in secondary school for the period 1960-1985. specifications that do not consider out-of-steady-state dynamics. Similarly, the greater importance of departures from steady state for the OECD would explain the finding of greater unconditional convergence. We find this interpretation plausible: World War II surely caused large departures from the steady state, and it surely had larger effects on the OECD than on the rest of the world. With a value of X of 0.02, almost half of the departure from steady state in 1945 would have remained by the end of our sample in 1985. Overall, our interpretation of the evidence on convergence contrasts sharply with that of endogenous-growth advocates. In particular, we believe that the study of convergence does not show a failure of the Solow model. After controlling for those
  • 61. variables that the Solow model says determine the steady state, there is substantial convergence in income per capita. Moreover, conver- gence occurs at approximately the rate that the model predicts. This content downloaded from 141.241.43.86 on Tue, 21 Oct 2014 08:12:36 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp 430 QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS IV. INTEREST RATE DIFFERENTIALS AND CAPITAL MOVEMENTS Recently, several economists, including Lucas [1988], Barro [1989], and King and Rebelo [1989], have emphasized an objection to the Solow model in addition to those we have addressed so far: they argue that the model fails to explain either rate-of-return differences or international capital flows. In the models of Sections I and II, the steady-state marginal product of capital, net of depreciation, is (17) MPK- 8 = u(n+ g + 8Sk Thus, the marginal product of capital varies positively with the population growth rate and negatively with the saving rate. Because the cross-country differences in saving and population growth rates are large, the differences in rates of return should also
  • 62. be large. For example, if at = 1/3, 8 = 0.03, and g = 0.02, then the mean of the steady-state net marginal product is 0.12 in the intermediate sample, and the standard deviation is 0.08.13 Two related facts seem inconsistent with these predictions. First, observed differentials in real interest rates appear smaller than the predicted differences in the net marginal product of capital. Second, as Feldstein and Horioka [1980] first documented, countries with high saving rates have high rates of domestic investment rather than large current account surpluses: capital does not flow from high-saving countries to low-saving countries. Although these two facts indeed present puzzles to be resolved, it is premature to view them as a basis for rejecting the Solow model. The Solow model predicts that the marginal product of capital will be high in low-saving countries, but it does not necessarily predict that real interest rates will also be high. One can infer the marginal product of capital from real interest rates on financial assets only if investors are optimizing and capital markets are perfect. Both of these assumptions are questionable. It is 13. There is an alternative way of obtaining the marginal product of capital, which applies even outside of the steady state but requires an estimate of I and the assumption of no country-specific shifts to the production function. If one assumes that the returns on human and physical capital are equalized within each country, then one can show that the MPK is proportional toy(a+P- 1)/(a+P). Therefore, for the
  • 63. textbook Solow model in which a = 1/3 and I = 0, the MPK is inversely proportional to the square of output. As King and Rebelo [1989] and others have noted, the implied differences in rates of return across countries are incredibly large. Yet if a = 0 = 1/3, then the MPK is inversely proportional to the square root of output. In this case, the implied cross-country differences in the MPK are much smaller and are similar to those obtained with equation (17). This content downloaded from 141.241.43.86 on Tue, 21 Oct 2014 08:12:36 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp THE EMPIRICS OF ECONOMIC GROWTH 431 possible that some of the most productive investments in poor countries are in public capital, and that the behavior of the governments of poor countries is not socially optimal. In addition, it is possible that the marginal product of private capital is also high in poor countries, yet those economic agents who could make the productive investments do not do so because they face fi- nancing constraints or because they fear future expropriation. Some evidence for this interpretation comes from examining international variation in the rate of profit. If capital earns its marginal product, then one can measure the marginal product of capital as
  • 64. MPK=Ky That is, the return to capital equals capital's share in income (a) divided by the capital-output ratio (K/Y). The available evidence indicates that capital's share is roughly constant across counties. Sachs [1979, Table 3] presents factor shares for the G-7 countries. His figures show that variation in these shares across countries and over time is small.'4 By contrast, capital-output ratios vary substantially across countries: accumulating the investment data from Summers and Heston [1988] to produce estimates of the capital stock, one finds that low-saving countries have capital- output ratios near one and high-saving countries have capital- output ratios near three. Thus, direct measurement of the profit rate suggests that there is large international variation in the return to capital. The available evidence also indicates that expropriation risk is one reason that capital does not move to eliminate these differences in the profit rate. Williams [1975] examines the experience of foreign investment in developing countries from 1956 to 1972. He reports that, during this period, governments nationalized about 19 percent of foreign capital, and that compensation averaged about 41 percent of book value. It is hard to say precisely how much of the observed differences in profit rates this expropriation risk can explain. Yet, in view of this risk, it would be surprising if the 14. In particular, there is no evidence that rapid capital accumulation raises capital's share. Sachs [1979] reports that Japan's rapid accumulation in the 1960s
  • 65. and 1970s, for example, was associated with a rise in labor's share from 69 percent in 1962-1964 to 77 percent in 1975-1978. See also Atkinson [1975, p. 167]. This content downloaded from 141.241.43.86 on Tue, 21 Oct 2014 08:12:36 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp 432 QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS profit rates were not at least somewhat higher in developing countries. Further evidence on rates of return comes from the large literature on international differences in the return to education. Psacharopoulos [1985] summarizes the results of studies for over 60 countries that analyze the determinants of labor earnings using micro data. Because forgone wages are the primary cost of educa- tion, the rate of return is roughly the percentage increase in the wage resulting from an additional year of schooling. He reports that the poorer the country, the larger the return to schooling. Overall, the evidence on the return to capital appears consis- tent with the Solow model. Indeed, one might argue that it supports the Solow model against the alternative of endogenous- growth models. Many endogenous-growth models assume constant returns to scale in the reproducible factors of production; they therefore imply that the rate of return should not vary with the
  • 66. level of development. Yet direct measurement of profit rates and returns to schooling indicates that the rate of return is much higher in poor countries. CONCLUSION We have suggested that international differences in income per capita are best understood using an augmented Solow growth model. In this model output is produced from physical capital, human capital, and labor, and is used for investment in physical capital, investment in human capital, and consumption. One production function that is consistent with our empirical results is Y= K1/3H1"31/3. This model of economic growth has several implications. First, the elasticity of income with respect to the stock of physical capital is not substantially different from capital's share in income. This conclusion indicates, in contrast to Romer's suggestion, that capital receives approximately its social return. In other words, there are not substantial externalities to the accumulation of physical capital. Second, despite the absence of externalities, the accumulation of physical capital has a larger impact on income per capita than the textbook Solow model implies. A higher saving rate leads to higher income in steady state, which in turn leads to a higher level of human capital, even if the rate of human-capital accumulation is This content downloaded from 141.241.43.86 on Tue, 21 Oct 2014 08:12:36 AM
  • 67. All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp THE EMPIRICS OF ECONOMIC GROWTH 433 unchanged. Higher saving thus raises total factor productivity as it is usually measured. This difference between the textbook model and the augmented model is quantitatively important. The text- book Solow model with a capital share of one third indicates that the elasticity of income with respect to the saving rate is one half. Our augmented Solow model indicates that this elasticity is one. Third, population growth also has a larger impact on income per capita than the textbook model indicates. In the textbook model higher population growth lowers income because the available capital must be spread more thinly over the population of workers. In the augmented model human capital also must be spread more thinly, implying that higher population growth lowers measured total factor productivity. Again, this effect is important quantita- tively. In the textbook model with a capital share of one third, the elasticity of income per capita with respect to n + g + 8 is - '/2. In our augmented model this elasticity is -2. Fourth, our model has implications for the dynamics of the economy when the economy is not in steady state. In contrast to
  • 68. endogenous-growth models, this model predicts that countries with similar technologies and rates of accumulation and population growth should converge in income per capita. Yet this convergence occurs more slowly than the textbook Solow model suggests. The textbook Solow model implies that the economy reaches halfway to steady state in about 17 years, whereas our augmented Solow model implies that the economy reaches halfway in about 35 years. More generally, our results indicate that the Solow model is consistent with the international evidence if one acknowledges the importance of human as well as physical capital. The augmented Solow model says that differences in saving, education, and popula- tion growth should explain cross-country differences in income per capita. Our examination of the data indicates that these three variables do explain most of the international variation. Future research should be directed at explaining why the variables taken to be exogenous in the Solow model vary so much from country to country. We expect that differences in tax policies, education policies, tastes for children, and political stability will end up among the ultimate determinants of cross-country differ- ences. We also expect that the Solow model will provide the best framework for understanding how these determinants influence a
  • 69. country's level of economic well-being. This content downloaded from 141.241.43.86 on Tue, 21 Oct 2014 08:12:36 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp 434 QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS APPENDIX GDP/ Growth Sample adult 1960-1985 I/Y SCHOOL working Number Country N I 0 1960 1985 GDP age pop 1 Algeria 1 1 0 2485 4371 4.8 2.6 24.1 4.5 2 Angola 1 0 0 1588 1171 0.8 2.1 5.8 1.8 3 Benin 1 0 0 1116 1071 2.2 2.4 10.8 1.8 4 Botswana 1 1 0 959 3671 8.6 3.2 28.3 2.9 5 Burkina Faso 1 0 0 529 857 2.9 0.9 12.7 0.4 6 Burundi 1 0 0 755 663 1.2 1.7 5.1 0.4 7 Cameroon 1 1 0 889 2190 5.7 2.1 12.8 3.4 8 CentralAfr. Rep. 1 0 0 838 789 1.5 1.7 10.5 1.4 9 Chad 1 0 0 908 462 -0.9 1.9 6.9 0.4 10 Congo, Peop. Rep. 1 0 0 1009 2624 6.2 2.4 28.8 3.8 11 Egypt 1 0 0 907 2160 6.0 2.5 16.3 7.0 12 Ethiopia 1 1 0 533 608 2.8 2.3 5.4 1.1 13 Gabon 0 0 0 1307 5350 7.0 1.4 22.1 2.6 14 Gambia, The 0 0 0 799 3.6 18.1 1.5 15 Ghana 1 0 0 1009 727 1.0 2.3 9.1 4.7 16 Guinea 0 0 0 746 869 2.2 1.6 10.9
  • 70. 17 Ivory Coast 1 1 0 1386 1704 5.1 4.3 12.4 2.3 18 Kenya 1 1 0 944 1329 4.8 3.4 17.4 2.4 19 Lesotho 0 0 0 431 1483 6.8 1.9 12.6 2.0 20 Liberia 1 0 0 863 944 3.3 3.0 21.5 2.5 21 Madagascar 1 1 0 1194 975 1.4 2.2 7.1 2.6 22 Malawi 1 1 0 455 823 4.8 2.4 13.2 0.6 23 Mali 1 1 0 737 710 2.1 2.2 7.3 1.0 24 Mauritania 1 0 0 777 1038 3.3 2.2 25.6 1.0 25 Mauritius 1 0 0 1973 2967 4.2 2.6 17.1 7.3 26 Morocco 1 1 0 1030 2348 5.8 2.5 8.3 3.6 27 Mozambique 1 0 0 1420 1035 1.4 2.7 6.1 0.7 28 Niger 1 0 0 539 841 4.4 2.6 10.3 0.5 29 Nigeria 1 1 0 1055 1186 2.8 2.4 12.0 2.3 30 Rwanda 1 0 0 460 696 4.5 2.8 7.9 0.4 31 Senegal 1 1 0 1392 1450 2.5 2.3 9.6 1.7 32 Sierra Leone 1 0 0 511 805 3.4 1.6 10.9 1.7 33 Somalia 1 0 0 901 657 1.8 3.1 13.8 1.1 34 S. Africa 1 1 0 4768 7064 3.9 2.3 21.6 3.0 35 Sudan 1 0 0 1254 1038 1.8 2.6 13.2 2.0 36 Swaziland 0 0 0 817 7.2 17.7 3.7 37 Tanzania 1 1 0 383 710 5.3 2.9 18.0 0.5 38 Togo 1 0 0 777 978 3.4 2.5 15.5 2.9 39 Tunisia 1 1 0 1623 3661 5.6 2.4 13.8 4.3 40 Uganda 1 0 0 601 667 3.5 3.1 4.1 1.1 41 Zaire 1 0 0 594 412 0.9 2.4 6.5 3.6 42 Zambia 1 1 0 1410 1217 2.1 2.7 31.7 2.4 43 Zimbabwe 1 1 0 1187 2107 5.1 2.8 21.1 4.4 This content downloaded from 141.241.43.86 on Tue, 21 Oct 2014 08:12:36 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp THE EMPIRICS OF ECONOMIC GROWTH 435
  • 71. APPENDIX (CONTINUED) GDP/ Growth Sample adult 1960-1985 I/Y SCHOOL working Number Country N I 0 1960 1985 GDP age pop 44 Afghanistan 0 0 0 1224 1.6 6.9 0.9 45 Bahrain 0 0 0 30.0 12.1 46 Bangladesh 1 1 0 846 1221 4.0 2.6 6.8 3.2 47 Burma 1 1 0 517 1031 4.5 1.7 11.4 3.5 48 Hong Kong 1 1 0 3085 13,372 8.9 3.0 19.9 7.2 49 India 1 1 0 978 1339 3.6 2.4 16.8 5.1 50 Iran 0 0 0 3606 7400 6.3 3.4 18.4 6.5 51 Iraq 0 0 0 4916 5626 3.8 3.2 16.2 7.4 52 Israel 1 1 0 4802 10,450 5.9 2.8 28.5 9.5 53 Japan 1 1 1 3493 13,893 6.8 1.2 36.0 10.9 54 Jordan 1 1 0 2183 4312 5.4 2.7 17.6 10.8 55 Korea, Rep. of 1 1 0 1285 4775 7.9 2.7 22.3 10.2 56 Kuwait 0 0 0 77,881 25,635 2.4 6.8 9.5 9.6 57 Malaysia 1 1 0 2154 5788 7.1 3.2 23.2 7.3 58 Nepal 1 0 0 833 974 2.6 2.0 5.9 2.3 59 Oman 0 0 0 15,584 3.3 15.6 2.7 60 Pakistan 1 1 0 1077 2175 5.8 3.0 12.2 3.0 61 Philippines 1 1 0 1668 2430 4.5 3.0 14.9 10.6 62 Saudi Arabia 0 0 0 6731 11,057 6.1 4.1 12.8 3.1 63 Singapore 1 1 0 2793 14,678 9.2 2.6 32.2 9.0 64 Sri Lanka 1 1 0 1794 2482 3.7 2.4 14.8 8.3 65 Syrian Arab Rep. 1 1 0 2382 6042 6.7 3.0 15.9 8.8 66 Taiwan 0 0 0 8.0 20.7 67 Thailand 1 1 0 1308 3220 6.7 3.1 18.0 4.4 68 U. Arab Emirates 0 0 0 18,513 26.5
  • 72. 69 Yemen 0 0 0 1918 2.5 17.2 0.6 70 Austria 1 1 1 5939 13,327 3.6 0.4 23.4 8.0 71 Belgium 1 1 1 6789 14,290 3.5 0.5 23.4 9.3 72 Cyprus 0 0 0 2948 5.2 31.2 8.2 73 Denmark 1 1 1 8551 16,491 3.2 0.6 26.6 10.7 74 Finland 1 1 1 6527 13,779 3.7 0.7 36.9 11.5 75 France 1 1 1 7215 15,027 3.9 1.0 26.2 8.9 76 Germany, Fed. Rep. 1 1 1 7695 15,297 3.3 0.5 28.5 8.4 77 Greece 1 1 1 2257 6868 5.1 0.7 29.3 7.9 78 Iceland 0 0 0 8091 3.9 29.0 10.2 79 Ireland 1 1 1 4411 8675 3.8 1.1 25.9 11.4 80 Italy 1 1 1 4913 11,082 3.8 0.6 24.9 7.1 81 Luxembourg 0 0 0 9015 2.8 26.9 5.0 82 Malta 0 0 0 2293 6.0 30.9 7.1 83 Netherlands 1 1 1 7689 13,177 3.6 1.4 25.8 10.7 84 Norway 1 1 1 7938 19,723 4.3 0.7 29.1 10.0 This content downloaded from 141.241.43.86 on Tue, 21 Oct 2014 08:12:36 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp 436 QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS APPENDIX (CONTINUED) GDPI Growth Sample adult 1960-1985 I/Y SCHOOL working Number Country N I 0 1960 1985 GDP age pop
  • 73. 85 Portugal 1 1 1 2272 5827 4.4 0.6 22.5 5.8 86 Spain 1 1 1 3766 9903 4.9 1.0 17.7 8.0 87 Sweden 1 1 1 7802 15,237 3.1 0.4 24.5 7.9 88 Switzerland 1 1 1 10,308 15,881 2.5 0.8 29.7 4.8 89 Turkey 1 1 1 2274 4444 5.2 2.5 20.2 5.5 90 United Kingdom 1 1 1 7634 13,331 2.5 0.3 18.4 8.9 91 Barbados 0 0 0 3165 4.8 19.5 12.1 92 Canada 1 1 1 10,286 17,935 4.2 2.0 23.3 10.6 93 Costa Rica 1 1 0 3360 4492 4.7 3.5 14.7 7.0 94 Dominican Rep. 1 1 0 1939 3308 5.1 2.9 17.1 5.8 95 El Salvador 1 1 0 2042 1997 3.3 3.3 8.0 3.9 96 Guatemala 1 1 0 2481 3034 3.9 3.1 8.8 2.4 97 Haiti 1 1 0 1096 1237 1.8 1.3 7.1 1.9 98 Honduras 1 1 0 1430 1822 4.0 3.1 13.8 3.7 99 Jamaica 1 1 0 2726 3080 2.1 1.6 20.6 11.2 100 Mexico 1 1 0 4229 7380 5.5 3.3 19.5 6.6 101 Nicaragua 1 1 0 3195 3978 4.1 3.3 14.5 5.8 102 Panama 1 1 0 2423 5021 5.9 3.0 26.1 11.6 103 Trinidad & Tobago 1 1 0 9253 11,285 2.7 1.9 20.4 8.8 104 United States 1 1 1 12,362 18,988 3.2 1.5 21.1 11.9 105 Argentina 1 1 0 4852 5533 2.1 1.5 25.3 5.0 106 Bolivia 1 1 0 1618 2055 3.3 2.4 13.3 4.9 107 Brazil 1 1 0 1842 5563 7.3 2.9 23.2 4.7 108 Chile 1 1 0 5189 5533 2.6 2.3 29.7 7.7 109 Colombia 1 1 0 2672 4405 5.0 3.0 18.0 6.1 110 Ecuador 1 1 0 2198 4504 5.7 2.8 24.4 7.2 111 Guyana 0 0 0 2761 1.1 32.4 11.7 112 Paraguay 1 1 0 1951 3914 5.5 2.7 11.7 4.4 113 Peru 1 1 0 3310 3775 3.5 2.9 12.0 8.0 114 Surinam 0 0 0 3226 4.5 19.4 8.1 115 Uruguay 1 1 0 5119 5495 0.9 0.6 11.8 7.0 116 Venezuela 1 1 0 10,367 6336 1.9 3.8 11.4 7.0 117 Australia 1 1 1 8440 13,409 3.8 2.0 31.5 9.8 118 Fiji 0 0 0 3634 4.2 20.6 8.1 119 Indonesia 1 1 0 879 2159 5.5 1.9 13.9 4.1
  • 74. 120 New Zealand 1 1 1 9523 12,308 2.7 1.7 22.5 11.9 121 Papua New Guinea 1 0 0 1781 2544 3.5 2.1 16.2 1.5 Note. Growth rates are in percent per year. IIY is investment as a percentage of GDP, and SCHOOL is the percentage of the working-age population in secondary school, both averaged for the period 1960-1985. N, I, and 0 denote the non-oil, intermediate, and OECD samples. This content downloaded from 141.241.43.86 on Tue, 21 Oct 2014 08:12:36 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp THE EMPIRICS OF ECONOMIC GROWTH 437 HARVARD UNIVERSITY UNIVERSITY OF CALIFORNIA AT BERKELEY BROWN UNIVERSITY REFERENCES Atkinson, Anthony, The Economics of Inequality (Oxford: Clarendon Press, 1975). Azariadis, Costas, and Allan Drazen, "Threshold Externalities in Economic Development," Quarterly Journal of Economics, CV (1990), 501-26. Barro, Robert J., "Economic Growth in a Cross Section of Countries," NBER Working Paper 3120, September 1989.
  • 75. De Long, J. Bradford, "Productivity Growth, Convergence, and Welfare: Comment," American Economic Review, LXXVIII (1988), 1138-54. Dowrick, Steve, and Duc-Tho Nguyen, "OECD Comparative Economic Growth 1950-85: Catch-Up and Convergence," American Economic Review, LXXIX (1989),1010-30. Easterlin, Richard, "Why Isn't the Whole World Developed?" Journal of Economic History, XLI (1981),1-20. Feldstein, Martin, and Charles Horioka, "Domestic Saving and International Capital Flows," Economic Journal, XC (1980), 314-29. Kendrick, John W., The Formation and Stocks of Total Capital (New York: Columbia University for NBER, 1976). King, Robert G., and Sergio T. Rebelo, "Transitional Dynamics and Economic Growth in the Neoclassical Model," NBER Working Paper 3185, November 1989. Krueger, Anne O., "Factor Endowments and per Capita Income Differences Among Countries," Economic Journal, LXXVIII (1968), 641-59. Lucas, Robert E. Jr., "On the Mechanics of Economic Development," Journal of Monetary Economics, XXII (1988), 3-42.
  • 76. Psacharopoulos, George, "Returns to Education: A Further International Update and Implications," Journal of Human Resources, XX (1985), 583-604. Rauch, James E., "The Question of International Convergence of per Capita Consumption: An Euler Equation Approach," mimeo, August 1988, University of California at San Diego. Romer, Paul, "Crazy Explanations for the Productivity Slowdown," NBER Macro- economicsAnnual, 1987,163-210. Capital Accumulation in the Theory of Long Run Growth," Modern Business Cycle Theory, Robert J. Barro, ed. (Cambridge, MA: Harvard Univer- sity Press, 1989a), pp. 51-127. "Human Capital and Growth: Theory and Evidence," NBER Working Paper 3173, November 1989b. Sachs, Jeffrey D., "Wages, Profit, and Macroeconomic Adjustment: A Comparative Study," Brookings Papers on Economic Activity (1979:2), 269- 332. Solow, Robert M., "A Contribution to the Theory of Economic Growth," Quarterly Journal of Economics, LXX (1956), 65-94. Summers, Robert, and Alan Heston, "A New Set of International
  • 77. Comparisons of Real Product and Price Levels Estimates for 130 Countries, 1950-85," Review of Income and Wealth, XXXIV (1988),1-26. Williams, M. L., "The Extent and Significance of Nationalization of Foreign-owned Assets in Developing Countries, 1956-1972," Oxford Economic Papers, XXVII (1975), 260-73. This content downloaded from 141.241.43.86 on Tue, 21 Oct 2014 08:12:36 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jspArticle Contentsp. [407]p. 408p. 409p. 410p. 411p. 412p. 413p. 414p. 415p. 416p. 417p. 418p. 419p. 420p. 421p. 422p. 423p. 424p. 425p. 426p. 427p. 428p. 429p. 430p. 431p. 432p. 433p. 434p. 435p. 436p. 437Issue Table of ContentsThe Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 107, No. 2 (May, 1992), pp. 327-796Front MatterVoters as Fiscal Conservatives [pp. 327-361]On Diversity [pp. 363-405]A Contribution to the Empirics of Economic Growth [pp. 407-437]Job Mobility and the Careers of Young Men [pp. 439-479]Why is Production More Volatile than Sales? Theory and Evidence on the Stockout-Avoidance Motive for Inventory-Holding [pp. 481-510]Asymmetric Tournaments, Equal Opportunity Laws, and Affirmative Action: Some Experimental Results [pp. 511-539]Economics of Direct Legislation [pp. 541-571]Anomalies in Intertemporal Choice: Evidence and an Interpretation [pp. 573-597]Judging Factor Abundance [pp. 599-620]Why Do Countries and Industries with Large Seasonal Cycles Also Have Large Business Cycles? [pp. 621-656]Market Structure and the Nature of Price Rigidity: Evidence from the Market for Consumer Deposits [pp. 657- 680]Coordination in Split Award Auctions [pp. 681-707]How
  • 78. Well Does the IS-LM Model Fit Postwar U.S. Data? [pp. 709- 738]Communication in Coordination Games [pp. 739- 771]Financial Assets, Inflation Hedges, and Capital Utilization in Developing Countries: An Extension of McKinnon's Complementarity Hypothesis [pp. 773-784]Optimal Financial Contracting with Ex Post and Ex Ante Observability Problems [pp. 785-795]Back Matter [pp. 796-796] Eviews.wf1 Gretl.gdt Gretl.gdt 18 Nov 2008 16:55 Data imported from Stata file 'mrw.dta', 2014-10-10 14:48 1 1 1 1 0 2485 4371 4.8000001907348633 2.5999999046325684 24.100000381469727 4.5 2 2 1 0 0 1588 1171 0.80000001192092896 2.0999999046325684 5.8000001907348633 1.7999999523162842
  • 79. 3 3 1 0 0 1116 1071 2.2000000476837158 2.4000000953674316 10.800000190734863 1.7999999523162842 4 4 1 1 0 959 3671 8.6000003814697266 3.2000000476837158 28.299999237060547 2.9000000953674316 5 5 1 0 0 529 857 2.9000000953674316 0.89999997615814209 12.699999809265137 0.40000000596046448 6 6 1 0 0 755 663 1.2000000476837158 1.7000000476837158 5.0999999046325684 0.40000000596046448 7 7 1 1 0 889 2190 5.6999998092651367 2.0999999046325684 12.800000190734863 3.4000000953674316 8 8 1 0 0 838 789 1.5 1.7000000476837158 10.5 1.3999999761581421 9 9 1 0 0 908 462 -0.89999997615814209 1.8999999761581421 6.9000000953674316 0.40000000596046448 10 10 1 0 0 1009 2624 6.1999998092651367 2.4000000953674316 28.799999237060547 3.7999999523162842 11 11 1 0 0 907 2160 6 2.5 16.299999237060547 7 12 12 1 1 0 533 608 2.7999999523162842 2.2999999523162842 5.4000000953674316 1.1000000238418579 13 13 0 0 0 1307 5350 7 1.3999999761581421 22.100000381469727 2.5999999046325684 14 14 0 0 0 799 NA 3.5999999046325684 NA 18.100000381469727 1.5 15 15 1 0 0 1009 727 1 2.2999999523162842 9.1000003814697266 4.6999998092651367 16 16 0 0 0 746 869 2.2000000476837158 1.6000000238418579 10.899999618530273 NA 17 17 1 1 0 1386 1704 5.0999999046325684 4.3000001907348633 12.399999618530273 2.2999999523162842 18 18 1 1 0 944 1329 4.8000001907348633 3.4000000953674316 17.399999618530273 2.4000000953674316