SlideShare a Scribd company logo
1 of 20
Download to read offline
DOI 10.14746/ssp.2018.3.7
Paweł Błaszczyk
Poznań University of Economics and Business
Łukasz Fojutowski
Collegium Da Vinci
Convergence of price dynamics assessed
in view of Poland’s accession
to the euro area focusing on deflation
Abstract: The primary aim of this study was to assess the degree of Poland’s con-
vergence in terms of price stability, both at the stage of the country’s candidacy to the
euro area and in relation to the euro convergence criteria (the so-called Maastricht
criteria), and in the broader context of the ECB’s unified monetary policy. The time
frame for this study covers the period of 2004–2017. The starting point marks Po-
land’s accession to the EU, which is a pre-requisite for application to access the euro
area. The closing time was chosen due to the availability of data, mainly from the Eu-
rostat database. This was studied in view of the critical analysis of methodology and
the method used to establish the Maastricht criterion for the dynamics of the general
price level. The methodology of determining the inflation criterion is flawed and not
matched to today’s economic conditions, including the definition of price stability ap-
plied in the practice of central banking, as well as in the context of the phenomenon of
deflation commonly occurring in the last decade. As a consequence, the value of the
criterion for a candidate country may turn out to be very low, and may unjustifiably
increase the costs of accession to the euro area, also in the long-term perspective. Such
a problem should be taken into account in the discussion on Poland’s accession to the
euro area, which is usually of a political, as well as social and economic nature. This
economic aspect, however, should be key in practice.
Key words: deflation, economic integration, euro area, monetary policy, price stability
Introduction
European integration processes lasting many decades now have been
strongly connected with the process of convergence, understood as
the process of economies becoming increasingly similar, which leads to
their convergence. On the one hand, convergence is a pre-condition for
100	 Paweł Błaszczyk, Łukasz Fojutowski	 ŚSP 3 ’18
integration, while on the other hand it is its objective, which is to con-
tribute to the socio-economic growth and development of united Europe.
When we consider the European Union (EU) and the euro area (EA) as
a certain stage in the overall integration process (Molle, 2000, part I ff.),
which may be termed as an incomplete economic and monetary union
(De Grauwe, 2003, pp. 107–140; Zwierzchlewski, 2015, Chapter 1), we
need to stress that certain conditions need to be met to participate, such
as those related to economic convergence, both in terms of membership
of the EU and next also of the EA. In turn, accession to such associations
may promote convergence, as indicated e.g. by the structure and scale
of the EU budget. Fiscal policy in Europe is primarily executed at the
national level (both central and local governments), while the EU budget
is mainly to ensure redistribution in order to enhance socio-economic co-
hesion within more specific areas (see EU budget structure). However,
its excessive growth and incorporation of a wider range of fiscal func-
tions outside the area of convergence are considered disadvantageous, as
evidenced by the limit for its volume established at 1.24% of the GDP of
member countries.1
Also in the monetary (currency) aspect, convergence is inseparably
associated with European integration. In this sense, it refers first of all to
the Maastricht criteria as pre-conditions for accession to the euro area.
However, these should not be considered solely as boundary conditions
to be met in order to access the European Monetary Union, but rather as
a completion and verification of the conclusion for the convergence proc-
ess in relation to the applicant country. This study is focused on the cri-
terion related to price stability and more broadly speaking – to the entire
convergence process in this area in view of accession and membership in
the Monetary Union (compare Ochryniuk, Rogut, 2010). This is connect-
ed with serious problems, not only for the euro area candidate country
which has to meet the requirement not only before, but also after acces-
sion; a problem lies also in the methodology of establishing the criterion
itself. The above-mentioned problems discussed within this study have
a significant impact on the balance of costs and benefits connected with
accession to the zone of the common European currency (De Grauwe,
2003, Chapters 1–4). Divergence in the dynamics of the general price
level not only hinders accession to the euro area and makes it more costly,
but also leads to incompatibility with the EU’s unified monetary policy of
1
  For more on the EU budget and its rules see: e.g. Zombirt (2008, pp. 455–489).
ŚSP 3 ’18	 Convergence of price dynamics assessed in view of Poland’s...	 101
the European Central Bank (ECB) and generates resulting participation
costs (Błaszczyk, 2016).
This is a particularly important issue from the point of view of the chal-
lenges of economic policy in Poland in the face of accession to the euro
area. An economic analysis of the balance of costs and benefits should be
the basis for the discussion on making the final political decision on the
date of accession – a decision which, however, is not only political and
economic, but also social in nature.2
Our decision-makers should con-
sider a number of factors regarding both the pre-accession process and
the conditions of belonging to the euro area, particularly in the face of
the crisis situations in European economic and monetary union in the
last decade (Walkowski, 2012). It should be emphasized that this article
focuses mainly on economic and monetary aspects of convergence with
the euro area.
In this context, the primary aim of this paper is to assess the degree of
Poland’s convergence in terms of price stability, both at the stage of our
candidacy to the euro area and in relation to the Maastricht criteria, and in
the broader context of the ECB’s unified monetary policy. These aspects
were studied in relation to the critical analysis of the methodology and
the method used to establish the Maastricht criterion for the dynamics of
the general price level. The time frame for the study covers the period of
2004–2017. The starting point marks Poland’s accession to the EU, which
is a pre-requisite for the application to access the euro area. The closing
time point results from the availability of data, mainly in relation to the
Eurostat database.
This study is composed of two basic parts. One concerns the method-
ology for the Maastricht inflation criterion.3
A critical analysis of it was
performed, indicating its incompatibility with current economic condi-
tions, particularly in view of the definitions of price stability applied in
central banking practice, as well as the deflation phenomena observed in
the last decade. The paper presents the phenomena which should be con-
2
  For a broad look at the balance of costs and benefits of Poland’s accession to the
euro area against the background of the economic convergence process see: e.g. NBP
(2009), Wójcik (2008), Pronobis (2008), Szeląg (1998).
3
  In view of the potential inclusion of reference countries experiencing deflation
in the establishment of the criterion, the term inflation criterion is incorrect. It should
rather be referred to as price stability or dynamics of the general price level. However,
in view of common use it was decided also to use the phrase inflation criterion in
this study.
102	 Paweł Błaszczyk, Łukasz Fojutowski	 ŚSP 3 ’18
sidered in the adaptation of the methodology, e.g. in the context of Mon-
etary Union, to be applied in the regional variation in the dynamics of the
general price level. In the following part, several variants for changes in
the methodology of the Maastricht inflation criterion are presented, and
then in this context nominal convergence in Poland is assessed.
1. Price stability and the Maastricht inflation criterion
The Maastricht inflation criterion is one of the five primary nominal
pre-conditions for accession to the EA. The other criteria concern long-
term interest rates and government debt, as well as exchange rates. The
idea underlying these criteria is to achieve and maintain a specific degree
of convergence which will determine the balance of costs and benefits of
EAmembership. Economic convergence of the countries promotes the in-
creased effectiveness and efficiency of the ECB’s unified monetary policy.
Countries which deviate from the EA average may incur losses resulting
from the incompatibility of the unified policy with domestic economic
conditions, particularly the dynamics of the general price level. This may
result in one of the most often stressed threats for accession to the EA,
i.e. loss of autonomy in monetary and exchange rate policies. In the case
of monetary divergence, the unified ECB instruments, established based
on the average parameters for EA and considering a 2% inflation target,
may be unsuitable for countries unable to meet the fixed parameters. For
example, in countries with the lowest inflation rates, or even deflation, the
EU monetary policy would become too restrictive (due to the high real
rate), having a negative effect on employment rates and domestic product,
while in countries with higher inflation rates it would be too expansive
(due to the low real rate), promoting further increases in inflation, instead
of stabilizing it at the level of the EA target. As a result, on the one hand
the situation on the labor market would deteriorate, while on the other
hand inflation trends would accelerate, e.g. in relation to the expected
inflation rate. In contrast, if convergence is properly executed, taking into
consideration long-term forecasts, and not only in view of meeting the
Maastricht criteria, the above-mentioned autonomy of national policies
will never be needed (or will only be needed rarely) and the unified ECB
policy will prove sufficient.
The idea of the inflation criterion for convergence is thus particularly
positive in the context of European integration, a process currently ob-
served at the level of economic and monetary policies, having already
covered the level of markets both for goods and services and factors of
production, including e.g. the stages of the free trade zone, customs union
ŚSP 3 ’18	 Convergence of price dynamics assessed in view of Poland’s...	 103
or the common market (Molle, 2000). However, doubts may be raised
on the one hand by the methodology used to establish this criterion4
and
on the other hand – by its implementation by the candidate countries and
their EA counterparts.
In relation to the concept of reaching a high level of sustainable con-
vergence within the euro area, the Treaty stipulates that one of the condi-
tions is “the achievement of a high degree of price stability; this will be
apparent from a rate of inflation which is close to that of, at most, the three
best performing Member States in terms of price stability” (Article 140 of
the Treaty on the Functioning of the European Union). According to Ar-
ticle 1 of the Protocol on the Convergence Criteria the level of inflation
in a given country within the year preceding the analysis may not exceed
the inflation rates in the three EU states with the most stable price levels
expressed in terms of HICP (Harmonised Index of Consumer Prices) by
more than 1.5 pp. The method of identifying reference countries raises
doubts. It is difficult to clearly define the term “best performing Member
States in terms of price stability.” Price stability can be an ambiguous
concept (Błaszczyk, 2010), particularly in relation to the quantitative as-
pect. Apart from the other aspects of the definition of price stability, par-
ticularly disregarding its potential measurement through the price level
path, and assuming the rate of change in the general price level, its target
value needs to be considered (Błaszczyk, 2010).
The European Commission is not consistent in the identification of
reference states, and thus in defining “the best performance in terms
of price stability.” Generally, countries with the lowest mean annual rate
of inflation are selected. A problem appeared in the case of zero and nega-
tive dynamics of the general price level. For example, in 2004, in the
Reports on Convergence the European Committee decided to eliminate
Lithuania from the group of reference countries, which at that time was
experiencing deflation measured using HICP. However, already in 2010,
with several EU countries reporting deflation (Ireland, Portugal, Estonia,
Belgium, Spain) the European Commission arbitrarily decided only to
eliminate Ireland, with the highest deflation rate, from the reference state
group. In the following years, when deflation was recorded worldwide,
in relation to decreasing prices of raw materials on the world markets,
including oil, countries with deflation were not rejected.
4
  An interesting collection of studies on the validity of the definition of price
stability as well as the entire ECB monetary policy strategy is available from the ECB
(2003).
104	 Paweł Błaszczyk, Łukasz Fojutowski	 ŚSP 3 ’18
In such a situation, apart from the fact that the investigated criterion
is relative in character and its variability may cause uncertainty regarding
an EA candidate country, it may prove to be undesirably low, including
values close to zero, or even hypothetically negative. We may thus ques-
tion whether it is justified to meet such a ‘reduced’ criterion, due to the
potential forcing of a considerable restriction of economic policy and re-
lated unjustified high costs. For example, a situation may arise in which
a candidate country would have to reduce an inflation level which under
normal conditions would be considered advantageous and optimal (e.g.
2.5%), to values considered harmful (close, equal to or below zero), since
this is indicated by the current situation in the euro area, specifically in
relation to only the three countries with the lowest price dynamics. Sur-
prisingly, the value of the criterion may be incompatible with the ECB’s
definition of price stability, indicating 2% inflation, while the idea behind
the implementation of this criterion is to achieve convergence with the
euro area and adaptation to the ‘average’ unified ECB policy, which de-
termines the long-term benefits from EAmembership. Why is the value of
the criterion to be determined by countries with the lowest price dynamics
(irrespective of the addition of 1.5 pp to the mean price dynamics in those
countries) and not, for example, those with medium dynamics, since the
ECB policy refers mainly to such a parameter? Thus, it is necessary to
discuss the redefinition of the price stability criterion, or at least to clearly
specify the concept of countries with the greatest price stability. To do
this, the notion of price stability needs to be analyzed.
It would seem that price stability is equivalent to zero inflation. How-
ever, hypothetically price stability may be defined in terms of a negative,
zero or positive rate of change in the general price level. Each solution
has its advantages and disadvantages; however, both empirical studies and
central banking practice definitely indicate a positive inflation target. The
value most commonly applied by countries using the direct inflation target-
ing strategy, assuming price stability as a primary objective, and specified
explicitly in the form of the inflation target falls within the range of 2–3%
(Błaszczyk, 2010). For example, inflation targets of the oldest central banks
worldwide, i.e. Sveriges Riksbank and the Bank of England, amount to 2%,
similarly as it is for the Federal Reserve System (since 2012) and the Bank
of Japan (since 2013). At present, the ECB defines price stability as infla-
tion below 2%, but close to that value, whereas for the National Bank of
Poland NBP it is 2.5% +/– 1 pp. Discussions on price stability indicate that
the reference countries being best performers in terms of price stability in
ŚSP 3 ’18	 Convergence of price dynamics assessed in view of Poland’s...	 105
relation to the Maastricht criterion should have this specified inflation level.
Taking into consideration the EU countries, and at the same time candidate
or EA countries, the term “the greatest price stability” should refer to the
ECB target, i.e. approx. 2% or slightly below that value, such as 1.5–2%
and possibly also above, considering the symmetry of the inflation target.
Thus, the candidate countries would strive to attain a target, which will later
be binding within the ECB’s unified monetary policy.
From the point of view of both the society and the economy, many
factors indicate the advisability of establishing a positive (non-zero and
non-negative) inflation target reflecting the optimal dynamics of the gen-
eral price level. They include e.g.:
downward nominal wage rigidity (Akerlof, Dickens, Perry, 1996, pp.––
1–59; Akerlof, Dickens, Perry, 2000; Keynes, 2003, pp. 231–244;
Kwiatkowski, 2002, p. 105; Wojtyna, 2004, p. 202; for Japan: Kimura,
Ueda, 1997; for the USA: Lebow, Saks, Wilson, 2003; for Switzer-
land: Fehr, Goette, 2000; for Germany: Knoppik, Beissinger, 2001:
for Sweden: Ekberg, 2002; for Great Britain: Nickell, Quintini, 2003,
and for Italy: Devicienti, 2004);
nominal interest rate floor (Wojtyna, 2001; IMF, 1999, p. 101; Sven-––
sson, 2000, pp. 27–28, 41);
risk of deflation (Kumar, Baig, Decressin, Faulkner-MacDonagh,––
Feyzioglu, 2003; Kilian, Manganelli, 2007, pp. 561–588);
overestimation of actual dynamics of the general price level (mainly––
CPI and similar measures) (Social Security Administration, 1996;
Friedman, 2002, pp. 89–90, Wynne, Rodriguez-Palenzuela, 2002);
seigniorage (Cukrowski, 2001);––
regional variation in dynamics of the general price level in the Mon-––
etary Union (Weber, Beck, 2005; Wójcik, 2008, pp. 106–142; Alda-
soro, Zdarek 2009; Błaszczyk, 2014; Błaszczyk, 2016).
In order to present these aspects in terms of the identification of the
inflation target we may use formula 1.
	 Π*
= ΠE
+ max {ΠDNWR
, ΠDNIRB
, ΠDT
, ΠRVPD
...}	 (1)
where:
Π*
– value of the inflation target,
ΠE
– value of error for inflation measurement,
ΠDNWR
– inflation rate considering downward nominal wage rigidity,
ΠDNIRB
– inflation rate constituting downward bound against nominal in-
terest rate floor,
106	 Paweł Błaszczyk, Łukasz Fojutowski	 ŚSP 3 ’18
ΠDT
– inflation rate hedging against other deflation threats, e.g. liquidity
trap or deflation spiral,
ΠRVPD
– inflation rate considering regional variation in price dynamics
within the Monetary Union.
The beginning of the formula needs to include an error for the meas-
ured dynamics in the general price level, above all overestimation.
Preferably, the errors should be eliminated, rather than included in the
target value. Thus, the factor differs from the others indicated in the
procedure, since their incorporation is, in reality, required to attain the
target inflation rate. The other phenomena are substitutionary in relation
to one another, i.e. the maximum inflation value resulting from each of
them provides a buffer against all the others. For this reason, this value
is added to the measurement error. The formula ends with an ellipsis to
indicate that other factors, more or less directly associated with defla-
tion conditions, may be included, e.g. inflation rate generated by the
profits from seigniorage. In view of current monetary policy, including
the independence of central banks, this argument is increasingly losing
importance, particularly in relation to Monetary Union. Estimates for
individual factors in this formula will differ for individual countries/
unions, and thus it is impossible to indicate a universal optimal value of
inflation target.
In the case of monetary union, such as in the euro area, an additional
factor will be connected with the regional diversity in the dynamics of
the general price level. This results first of all from the asymmetry of
shocks affecting various countries, and differences in the mechanisms
of their transmission. The reasons may stem from the regulations of the
product and labor markets (Moretti, 2014). In this context we should
also stress the role of the Harrod-Balassa-Samuelson effect (H-B-S). It
affects mainly those countries which are characterized by a relatively
high growth rate in the production efficiency of exchangeable goods.
This increase leads indirectly to a real, absorbable appreciation of cur-
rency, or nominal appreciation, or through a greater growth rate for do-
mestic prices. According to the H-B-S model, this mechanism consists
of a rapid growth in productivity in the exchangeable goods sector, lead-
ing to an increase in wages in that sector. This is because prices for
those goods are exogenous, and are determined on the world market.
Since we are dealing with perfect capital mobility between the sectors
of exchangeable and non-exchangeable goods, wages in the latter sec-
tor will also increase. However, the growth rate in productivity is lower.
ŚSP 3 ’18	 Convergence of price dynamics assessed in view of Poland’s...	 107
The increase in wages will be reflected in the growth of prices in the
non-exchangeable goods sector and as a consequence – in an increase
in the general price level.
Finally, countries with a high productivity growth rate (first of all
small, open emerging economies) will potentially have higher inflation in
comparison to countries with a lower growth rate, but not a lower level of
productivity (primarily more developed countries) (Chmielewski, 2003).
Inflation resulting from the H-B-S effect may be considered ‘good.’ This
may be termed as resulting from a reduced distance between more and
less developed economies. For this reason, it is not advisable to take ac-
tions to reduce such inflation. It should be first included in the ECB infla-
tion target, and secondly it needs to be incorporated in the methodology
for the Maastricht criterion.
An empirical assessment of regional differences in the general price
level dynamics in the euro area, as compared to that in the entire EU in
the years of 2004–2017, is presented in Fig. 1.
The data given in the top section of Fig. 1 refer to the maximum,
minimum and average price dynamics in EA countries. We can observe
a considerable variation in these values at the simultaneous extensive
deviations between them, which show no definite upward or downward
trend. It is also evident in the bottom figure as considerable changes in
the range, which for the EA falls within the range of <2.2, 6.3>, while
for standard deviation it is <0.63, 1.25>. In view of the low values of
inflation rates in the euro area countries and the ECB inflation target
itself, these differences turn out to be relatively large. It should also be
stressed here that the variation for the entire EU in the analyzed period
is much broader than for the euro area. In this case, the range is <2.7,
13.1>, while standard deviation is <0.62, 2.28>. Nevertheless, a posi-
tive result is connected with the increasing convergence of both meas-
ures for the EA and the EU in recent years, particularly since 2014.5
However, regional differences in the general price level dynamics in the
EA are evident, and this fact should be taken into consideration both in
the methodology for the criterion of nominal convergence and the value
of the ECB inflation target.
5
  Cf. research on the differences in price dynamics in the euro area with the use
of an interesting, different econometric methodology. The authors come to the conclu-
sion, which is confirmed in this article, that the analyzed differences should disappear
in the future, and additionally do not undermine the legitimacy of the inflation target
of the ECB (Weber, Beck, 2005).
108	 Paweł Błaszczyk, Łukasz Fojutowski	 ŚSP 3 ’18
Fig. 1. Assessment of regional differences in the general price level
dynamics in the euro area, as compared to that of the entire
European Union 2004–2017
6.0
5.0
4.0
3.0
2.0
1.0
0.0
–1.0
–2.0
%
2004
2005
2006
2007
2008
2009
2010
2011
2012
2013
2014
2015
2016
2017
max
EA – spread
min
EA – stand. dev.
average
EU – spread
Minimum, maximum and average general price level dynamics
in the euro area in 20042017
15.0
10.0
5.0
0.0
2004
2005
2006
2007
2008
2009
2010
2011
2012
2013
2014
2015
2016
2017
EU – stand. dev.
Range and standard deviation of general price level dynamics
in the euro area and the EU in 20042017
Source: Authors’ study based on Eurostat data.
ŚSP 3 ’18	 Convergence of price dynamics assessed in view of Poland’s...	 109
2. Assessment of Poland’s nominal convergence with the euro area
in terms of the general price level dynamics
The aim of the empirical study was to assess Poland’s convergence
with the euro area in terms of price dynamics, both in terms of short-term
compliance to the Maastricht criterion and long-term prospects for con-
formity to the ECB’s unified monetary policy. The analyzed period was
set as the years 2004–2017. The starting point marks Poland’s accession
to the EU and the resulting possibility to apply for accession to the euro
area. The closing time point is connected with the availability of data
for analysis.
Convergence was assessed taking into consideration both the Maas-
tricht criterion in its original form, and the authors’ proposal of a meth-
odology formulated based on the observations presented in the previous
chapter of this paper. In this context, several solutions modifying the
methodology for this criterion need to be proposed.
Eliminating from the EU reference group those countries, in which•	
deflation is recorded, and instead considering only countries with zero
and/or positive price dynamics, or possibly the adoption of a minimum
value of the criterion e.g. at 15%. In this way, a guarantee could be
provided for a protection barrier against deflation amounting to 1.5 pp.
A comparison of such a determined criterion to the methodology failing
to exclude countries experiencing deflation is presented in Fig. 2.
Establishment of the criterion at the level of the ECB inflation target•	
with an admissible fluctuation barrier, e.g. an arbitrary 0.5 pp. In this
way, we would ensure the stability of the criterion and the constancy
of its value for the candidate country, while the target would be sym-
metrical in character, i.e. it would treat inflation and deflation threats
equally, taking into consideration the antideflation barrier of 1.5 pp,
and additionally it would refer to the value which will be binding in
the long-term perspective of EA membership (Fig. 3).
Establishment of the criterion at the level of average price dynamics•	
in the euro area with the admissible fluctuation barrier, identified, for
example, based on the statistics concerning variation in price dynam-
ics within the EA (standard deviation, range, etc., see Fig. 3). The
strength of this variant stems from the fact that it refers to the situation
in which the current average price dynamics in the euro area deviates
from the target value of 2%. In this way, thus established, the crite-
rion would more effectively refer to the current economic situation,
110	 Paweł Błaszczyk, Łukasz Fojutowski	 ŚSP 3 ’18
and it would refer to the EA rather than the entire EU. Additionally,
this variant would take into consideration the general price level dy-
namics as an argument in the discussion on the inflation target value
(see formula 1). This methodology may also be supplemented by the
minimum upper level for the criterion (e.g. 1.5% or 2% – compare the
ECB target) (Fig. 3).
Price dynamics in Poland (HICP) in view of such formulated variants
of the criteria in the years 2004–2017 are presented in Figs. 2 and 3. In
Fig. 2, we can observe considerable differences in the criterion values
when comparing the original methodology assuming the incorporation
of reference countries experiencing deflation and the values obtained
when the above-mentioned countries are excluded from the analysis. The
differences are mainly evident in the years 2009–2010, i.e. during the
global financial and economic crisis, and 2013–2016, i.e. in the face of
downward trends in raw material prices, including oil prices on global
markets. In those years, except for 2013, the value of the criterion when
deflation was not excluded from analysis was dangerously low, drop-
ping below 1%. During the 14 investigated years, Poland would have
met the criterion 8 times, including the last 5 years, and interestingly,
this would be the case irrespective of the potential exclusion of the coun-
tries experiencing deflation. In recent years, despite the low value of the
criterion, price dynamics in Poland were also very low, and consistent
with the global trends in this respect in view of decreasing raw material
prices. This convergence was found under the effect of demand factors,
whereas during the crisis and the resulting negative demand shock (e.g.
in 2009) it was no longer observed. Macroeconomically, in that period,
our economy was in relatively good shape6
and for this reason it was not
subject to deflationary processes. However, if at that time it had been
necessary to meet the Maastricht criterion, restrictive monetary (or pos-
sibly fiscal) policies would have been required in order to adapt to the
‘unnaturally’ low criterion value, generating tremendous socio-economic
costs as a consequence. Additionally, taking into consideration reference
countries experiencing deflation would cause an absurd situation (see Fig.
2) in which in some years the ECB itself would not meet the Maastricht
criterion (see average price dynamics for the EA). Such a controversial
situation clearly shows the flaws of the currently applied methodology for
6
  It is evidenced by studies applying an original method based on a multifactorial
economic assessment measure (Błaszczyk, 2015).
ŚSP 3 ’18	 Convergence of price dynamics assessed in view of Poland’s...	 111
the Maastricht inflation criterion and thus it confirms the advisability of
its adjustment.
Thus, we can propose the exclusion of countries experiencing defla-
tion (Fig. 2) from the current methodology, which would result in the
minimum value of the criterion being 1.5%, i.e. at a level which in eco-
nomic central banking practice refers to the lower values considered opti-
mal in relation to price stability (compare the inflation target for Poland).
For example, such a methodological approach applied for the middle of
the 2009 crisis and under the global deflation trends in 2014–2016 would
result in the criterion value being arbitrarily limited and never dropping
below 1%, i.e. a value inconsistent with the contemporary definitions of
price stability in Europe and worldwide. Additionally, average price dy-
namics in the EA would take values below the criterion limit.
Fig. 2. Price dynamics in Poland and the EA in the years 2004–2017 in view
of the original methodology for the Maastricht criterion and following
the exclusion of countries experiencing deflation
5
4
3
2
1
0
–1
%
2004
2005
2006
2007
2008
2009
2010
2011
2012
2013
2014
2015
2016
2017
excluding deflation HICP Poland including deflation HICP EA
Source: Authors’ study based on Eurostat data.
While convergence in price dynamics is crucial in view of overall
economic integration in Europe, and at the present stage of compliance
with the unified monetary policy of the Monetary Union, a question arises
whether it should be verified in relation to EU member states, or rather
to countries with the lowest price dynamics. This is a major issue, since
112	 Paweł Błaszczyk, Łukasz Fojutowski	 ŚSP 3 ’18
the candidate country, in order to reduce the costs related to the loss of
autonomy in the monetary and exchange rate policies and the resulting
potential threat to the unified monetary policy, should adapt in terms of
price dynamics to the average trend in the euro area. It is the EA aver-
age, rather than the lowest price dynamics in the EU, that is the primary
benchmark for actions undertaken by the ECB and an element of the im-
pulse response function. Nevertheless, the former should be taken into
consideration within the multiparametric approach, including regional
variation in price dynamics (compare below).
For this reason, we need to consider the methodology of the crite-
rion referring to the ECB inflation target with the admissible fluctua-
tion barrier arbitrarily established at, say, 0.5%. In Figure 3, the upper
and lower values of such a determined criterion are marked with black
and red broken lines (the target plus 0.5, the target minus 0.5). In view
of the above, Poland would have serious problems with meeting the
accession criterion. The price dynamics is so unstable that it would
have fallen within the target range only in 2017, while it would have
exceeded it 7 times and been below it 5 times. While the proposed
methodology is justified logically and factually, in practice it might
prove too harsh for candidate countries (for comparison, see price dy-
namics for the EA).
Since price dynamics do not always need to comply with the ECB
target, e.g. due to global demand or supply trends, including those result-
ing from raw material prices, the next proposed change in the criterion
methodology refers to the average price dynamics in the EA. The cri-
terion would include admissible upward and downward fluctuations by
the value of standard deviation, possibly including the minimum value
of the criterion for the upper limit at 1.5 or 2% (which would refer to the
ECB target and ‘safe’ inflation values). This approach to a certain degree
would take into consideration regional variations in price dynamics and
the H-B-S effect. Such a specified criterion is shown in Fig. 3 as the black
(stand. dev. plus) and red (stand. dev. minus) dotted lines. In view of
the above, Poland would have met the criterion requirements 8 times, it
would have exceeded it 3 times, and Poland would have failed twice to
reach the lower limit by a slight margin.
This may be generally considered to be a good result, on the one
hand showing the correct choice of criterion methodology, while on the
other hand indicating the convergence of price dynamics in Poland with
that in the euro area. The first conclusion is difficult to verify defini-
ŚSP 3 ’18	 Convergence of price dynamics assessed in view of Poland’s...	 113
tively. However, further studies need to be conducted on the authors’
proposal for optimal inflation, focusing on the uniformity of the mon-
etary policy and price differentiations in the Monetary Union, even if it
seems factually sound and compliant with economic practice in terms
of price stability.
The second conclusion is doubtful, since price dynamics (see Figs. 2
and 3) in Poland for the entire period of analysis differed from that of the
EA and were less stable (except for 2017, with 1.6% and 1.5%, respec-
tively). In certain years, the price dynamic was greater, while in others it
was lower. The average for the 2004–2017 period for Poland was higher
and amounted to 2.1%, whereas for the EA it was 1.7%. The weak con-
vergence of price dynamics in Poland to that of the EA is presented more
comprehensively in Fig. 4 in relation to price levels (and not as previously
– the rate of changes in price dynamics).
Fig. 3. Price dynamics in Poland and the EA in the years 2004–2017
in view of proposed changes in the Maastricht criterion methodology
5.0
4.0
3.0
2.0
1.0
0.0
–1.0
%
2004
2005
2006
2007
2008
2009
2010
2011
2012
2013
2014
2015
2016
2017
stand. dev. (minus)
target (plus 0.5)
HICP Poland
stand. dev. (plus)
target (minus 0.5)
HICP EA
Source: Authors’ study based on Eurostat data.
114	 Paweł Błaszczyk, Łukasz Fojutowski	 ŚSP 3 ’18
Fig. 4. Price levels in Poland and in the EA in the years 2004–2017
with 2005 as the benchmark
130
120
110
100
90
EA Poland
2004M01
2004M09
2005M05
2006M01
2006M09
2007M05
2008M01
2008M09
2009M05
2010M01
2010M09
2011M05
2012M01
2012M09
2013M05
2014M01
2014M09
2015M05
2016M01
2016M09
2017M05
Source: Authors’ study based on Eurostat data.
In this approach, considerable convergence was observed in the period
until the global financial and economic crisis of the first decade of the
21st
century. Next, we can observe an increase in price levels in Poland
above the EA level, which is consistent with the fact that in a developing
country increased GDP dynamics B is accompanied by price dynamics.
The divergence in price levels stopped around 2013. Since then, we can
observe a degree of stabilization or even slight progress in convergence
for both time series.
Conclusion
The Polish economy is undergoing a continuous convergence process,
as it is developing in the context of European integration, and – particu-
larly – of the possible accession to the euro area. The necessary pre-con-
dition for the adoption of euro is connected with meeting the Maastricht
ŚSP 3 ’18	 Convergence of price dynamics assessed in view of Poland’s...	 115
criteria. In recent years, we have been witnessing progress in this field,
particularly in fiscal aspects. In terms of the monetary sphere analyzed in
this paper, particularly the general price level dynamics, in recent years
the inflation criterion would also have been met, both in terms of its origi-
nal methodology and the authors’ original proposal to adjust it.
However, this does not mean that the monetary authorities may have
no concerns over meeting the inflation criterion in the future, when the
political decision on accession to the euro area is finally made. In con-
trast, due to the relative character of this criterion its value is not certain.
In particular, the European and global economic situation, by affecting
domestic price dynamics including the reference countries, strongly de-
termines its level. The last decade at the global demand and supply eco-
nomic shocks and deflation showed that it may be very low, even close
to zero. There is no consensus on the identification of reference countries
experiencing deflation. As a consequence the criterion value may prove
very low, inconsistent with the ECB inflation target, and more broadly
with the definition of price stability applied in central banking practice
both in Europe and worldwide. Such a situation may irrationally increase
the costs associated with accession to the euro area also in the longer
time frame.
The methodology for establishing the Maastricht inflation criterion
should be modified to take into consideration the threat of excessively low
inflation, such as for example downward nominal wage rigidity, the lower
nominal interest rate limit as well as regional variation in price dynamics
in the Monetary Union. On the one hand, this methodology needs to treat
the inflation and deflation threat symmetrically, while on the other hand it
should also refer both to the average price dynamics in the euro area and
the ECB inflation target. The proposals contained in this paper meet these
requirements; nevertheless, further studies need to be conducted, e.g. also
including the experiences of countries other than Poland.
It should be taken into account that Poland’s accession to the euro
area, which has the status of a country with a derogation, is basically
a foregone conclusion. The question is not whether we want to enter the
Economic and Monetary Union, but when? The decision is mainly con-
ditioned by political will. The current economic situation, in particular
with regard to the nominal Maastricht criteria, is beneficial and provides
real grounds for their fulfillment in the coming years. Rational decision-
makers, in determining the date of accession, should therefore take into
account social and economic factors, including the criterion of price sta-
116	 Paweł Błaszczyk, Łukasz Fojutowski	 ŚSP 3 ’18
bility considered here, and not only purely political premises, including
electoral ones.
Bibliography
Akerlof G. A., Dickens W. T., Perry G. L. (1996), The Macroeconomics of Low Infla-
tion, Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, vol. 1.
Akerlof G. A., Dickens W. T., Perry G. L. (2000), Near-Rational Wage and Price Set-
ting and the Optimal Rates of Inflation and Unemployment, Brooking Papers
on Economic Activity, vol. 1.
Aldasoro J. I., Zdarek V. (2009), Inflation Differentials in the Euro Area and their De-
terminants – an empirical view, William Davidson Institute Working Paper,
no. 958, April.
Błaszczyk P. (2010), Stabilność cen – sposoby definicji oraz konsekwencje dla polityki
pieniężnej, Materiały i Studia NBP, no. 249.
Błaszczyk P. (2014), Wybrane problemy definicji stabilności cen w odniesieniu
do strefy euro in: Gospodarka w warunkach integracji europejskiej, eds.
D. J. Mierzejewski, J. Polcyn, Państwowa Wyższa Szkoła Zawodowa w Pile,
Piła, pp. 13–24.
Błaszczyk P. (2015), Post-crisis macroeconomic comparative assessment of the Eu-
rozone member states with the use of an improved misery index, “Journal of
Business & Economic Policy,” no. 3.
Błaszczyk P. (2016), Price Level Dynamics Differentiation as a Problem of Defini-
tion of Price Stability in the Euro Area, “Business Research Review,” vol. 2,
no. 1.
Chmielewski T. (2003), Od kursu płynnego do unii monetarnej. Znaczenie efektu
Balassy-Samuelsona dla polskiej polityki pieniężnej, “Materiały i Studia
NBP,” no. 163.
Cukrowski J. (2001), Renta emisyjna jako źródło finansowania budżetu państwa,
CASE, Warszawa.
De Grauwe P. (2003), Unia walutowa. Funkcjonowanie i wyzwania, PWE,
Warszawa.
Devicienti F. (2004), Downward Nominal Wage Rigidity in Italy: Evidence and Con-
sequences, LABORatorio R. Revelli Working Paper, no. 20.
ECB (2003), Background Studies for the ECB’s Evaluation of its Monetary Policy
Strategy, https://www.ecb.europa.eu/pub/pdf/other/monetarypolicystrat-
egyreview_backgrounden, 29.07.2018.
Ekberg J. (2002), Nominal Wage Rigidity on the Swedish Labor Market, Mimeo,
Stockholm School of Economics.
Fehr E., Goette L. (2000), Robustness and Real Consequences of Nominal Wage Ri-
gidity, “Journal of Monetary Economics,” vol. 52 no. 2005.
ŚSP 3 ’18	 Convergence of price dynamics assessed in view of Poland’s...	 117
Friedman B. L. (red.), Solow R. M., Taylor J. B. (2002), Inflacja, bezrobocie a poli-
tyka monetarna, CeDeWu, Warszawa.
IMF, International Monetary Fund (1999), Safeguarding Macroeconomic Stability at
Low Inflation, World Economic Outlook, October.
Keynes J. M. (2003), Ogólna teoria zatrudnienia, procentu i pieniądza, PWN,
Warszawa.
Kilian L., Manganelli S. (2007), Quantifying the Risk of Deflation, “Journal of Money,
Credit and Banking,” vol. 39, nos. 2–3.
Kimura T., Ueda K. (1997), Downward Nominal Wage Rigidity in Japan: Is Price
Stability Costly?, Bank of Japan Working Paper.
Knoppik C., Beissinger T. (2001), How Rigid are Nominal Wages? Evidence and Impli-
cations for Germany, “Scandinavian Journal of Monetary Economics,” no. 105.
Kumar M. S., Baig T., Decressin J., Faulkner-MacDonagh C., Feyzioglu T. (2003),
Deflation. Determinants, Risks, and Policy Options, International Monetary
Fund, Occasional Paper, no. 221.
Kwiatkowski E. (2002), Bezrobocie. Podstawy teoretyczne, PWN, Warszawa.
Lebow D. E., Saks R. E., Wilson B. A. (2003), Downward Nominal Wage Rigidity.
Evidence from the Employment Cost Index, “Advances in Macroeconomics,”
vol. 3.
Molle W. (2000), Ekonomika integracji europejskiej. Teoria, praktyka, polityka, Fun-
dacja Gospodarcza, Gdańsk.
Moretti L. (2014), Determinants of inflation differentials in the euro area, CFS Work-
ing Paper Series, no. 451, Center for Financial Studies.
NBP (2009), Raport na temat pełnego uczestnictwa Rzeczypospolitej Polskiej w trze-
cim etapie Unii Gospodarczej i Walutowej, Warszawa.
Nickell S. J., Quintini G. (2003), Nominal Wage Rigidity and the Rate of Inflation,
“Mimeo. The Economic Journal,” no. 113.
Ochryniuk M., Rogut A. (2010), Konwergencja nominalna w strefie euro. Implikacje
dla Polski, NBP, https://www.nbp.pl/publikacje/o_euro/konwergencja_nomi-
nalna.pdf. 30.07.2018.
Pronobis M. (2008), Polska w strefie euro, C.H. Beck, Warszawa.
Social Security Administration (1996), The Boskin Commission Report, Toward
a More Accurate Measure of the Cost of Living, https://www.ssa.gov/history/
reports/boskinrpt.html (30.01.2018)
Svensson L. E. O. (2000), How should monetary policy be conducted in an area of
price stability?, NBER Working Paper, no. 7516.
Szeląg K. (1998), Wprowadzenie euro – geneza, kluczowe decyzje, aspekty prawne,
„Bank i Kredyt,” no. 10.
Walkowski M. (2012), Unia Europejska – rozpad czy powrót do równowagi makro-
ekonomicznej i finansowej? Rozważania na temat kryzysu w strefie euro z per-
spektywy europejskiej i światowej, „Środkowoeuropejskie Studia Polityczne,”
no. 3.
118	 Paweł Błaszczyk, Łukasz Fojutowski	 ŚSP 3 ’18
Weber A. A., Beck G. W. (2005), Price Stability, Inflation Convergence and Diversity
in EMU: Does One Size Fit All?, Center for Financial Studies, no. 2005/30.
Wojtyna A. (2001), Skuteczność polityki pieniężnej w warunkach niskiej inflacji:
problem zerowej granicy nominalnych stóp procentowych, „Bank i Kredyt,”
no. 7.
Wojtyna A. (2004), Szkice o polityce pieniężnej, PWE, Warszawa.
Wójcik C. (2008), Integracja ze strefą euro. Teoretyczne i praktyczne aspekty konwer-
gencji, PWN, Warszawa.
Wynne M., Rodriguez-Palenzuela D. (2002), Measurement Bias in the HICP: What
Do We Know and What Do We Need to Know?, Federal Reserve Bank of Dal-
las Working Paper, no. 206.
Zombirt J. (2008), Mechanizmy rynku wewnętrznego Unii Europejskiej, Difin,
Warszawa.
Zwierzchlewski S. (2015), Stabilność unii walutowej, Wydawnictwo A. Marszałek,
Toruń.
Ocena konwergencji dynamiki cen w perspektywie akcesji Polski
do strefy euro ze szczególnym uwzględnieniem deflacji
Streszczenie
Podstawowym celem opracowania jest ocena stopnia konwergencji Polski w za-
kresie stabilności cen, zarówno na etapie kandydowania do strefy euro i w odniesieniu
do kryteriów z Maastricht, jak i w szerszym ujęciu w kontekście jednolitej polityki
pieniężnej EBC. Zakres czasowy badania obejmuje okres 2004–2017. Dolna cezura
czasowa wynika z przystąpienia Polski do UE, co warunkuje możliwość ubiegania się
o przynależność do strefy euro. Górna cezura czasowa wynika z dostępności danych,
głównie w odniesieniu do Eurostat. Realizacja celu została dokonana na tle analizy
krytycznej metodyki i sposobu wyznaczania kryterium z Maastricht dotyczącego dy-
namiki ogólnego poziomu cen. Metodyka wyznaczania kryterium inflacyjnego jest
wadliwa i niedopasowana do współczesnych uwarunkowań gospodarczych, w tym
na tle definicji stabilności cen stosowanych w praktyce bankowości centralnej, a tak-
że w kontekście zjawiska deflacji powszechnie występującego w ostatniej dekadzie.
W konsekwencji wartość kryterium dla kraju kandydującego może okazać się bar-
dzo niska i może w nieuzasadniony sposób zwiększać koszty akcesji do strefy euro,
również w długim horyzoncie czasowym. Taki problem powinien być uwzględniany
w dyskusji na temat akcesji Polski do strefy euro, która przeważnie ma charakter poli-
tyczny i dalej społeczny oraz ekonomiczny. To aspekt ekonomiczny jednak powinien
być w praktyce kluczowy.
Słowa kluczowe: deflacja, integracja gospodarcza, strefa euro, polityka pieniężna,
stabilność cen

More Related Content

What's hot

Memoire Viktoriya Dronova MCI-IAI(1)
Memoire Viktoriya Dronova MCI-IAI(1)Memoire Viktoriya Dronova MCI-IAI(1)
Memoire Viktoriya Dronova MCI-IAI(1)Victoria Isambert
 
Upharmacia - Ukrainian Pharma Market News Digest. October 2015
Upharmacia - Ukrainian Pharma Market News Digest. October 2015Upharmacia - Ukrainian Pharma Market News Digest. October 2015
Upharmacia - Ukrainian Pharma Market News Digest. October 2015Eirhub
 
Convergence Programme of Hungary 2011-2015 pdf download
Convergence Programme of Hungary 2011-2015 pdf downloadConvergence Programme of Hungary 2011-2015 pdf download
Convergence Programme of Hungary 2011-2015 pdf downloadHelyi Penz
 
Monetary Policies in the US and the Eurozone
Monetary Policies in the US and the EurozoneMonetary Policies in the US and the Eurozone
Monetary Policies in the US and the EurozoneDominik Holasek
 
Monthly Newsletter 12/2014
Monthly Newsletter 12/2014Monthly Newsletter 12/2014
Monthly Newsletter 12/2014Latvijas Banka
 
Hungary's National Reform Programme, pdf, download
Hungary's National Reform Programme, pdf, downloadHungary's National Reform Programme, pdf, download
Hungary's National Reform Programme, pdf, downloadHelyi Penz
 
An economic analysis on exchange rate and economic growth in bangladesh
An economic analysis on exchange rate and economic growth in bangladeshAn economic analysis on exchange rate and economic growth in bangladesh
An economic analysis on exchange rate and economic growth in bangladeshMahmudur Rahman
 
132 article text-185-1-10-20210523
132 article text-185-1-10-20210523132 article text-185-1-10-20210523
132 article text-185-1-10-20210523Arslan Ishaq
 
Swedbank Analysis: Competitiveness adjustment in Latvia
Swedbank Analysis: Competitiveness adjustment in LatviaSwedbank Analysis: Competitiveness adjustment in Latvia
Swedbank Analysis: Competitiveness adjustment in LatviaSwedbank
 

What's hot (20)

Ukraine, perspectives and state of reforms
Ukraine, perspectives and state of reformsUkraine, perspectives and state of reforms
Ukraine, perspectives and state of reforms
 
CASE Network Studies and Analyses 251 - Some Benefits of Reducing Inflation i...
CASE Network Studies and Analyses 251 - Some Benefits of Reducing Inflation i...CASE Network Studies and Analyses 251 - Some Benefits of Reducing Inflation i...
CASE Network Studies and Analyses 251 - Some Benefits of Reducing Inflation i...
 
CASE Network Studies and Analyses 423 - Fiscal policy in the EU in the crisis...
CASE Network Studies and Analyses 423 - Fiscal policy in the EU in the crisis...CASE Network Studies and Analyses 423 - Fiscal policy in the EU in the crisis...
CASE Network Studies and Analyses 423 - Fiscal policy in the EU in the crisis...
 
1 s2.0-s1049007814000220-main
1 s2.0-s1049007814000220-main1 s2.0-s1049007814000220-main
1 s2.0-s1049007814000220-main
 
Memoire Viktoriya Dronova MCI-IAI(1)
Memoire Viktoriya Dronova MCI-IAI(1)Memoire Viktoriya Dronova MCI-IAI(1)
Memoire Viktoriya Dronova MCI-IAI(1)
 
Upharmacia - Ukrainian Pharma Market News Digest. October 2015
Upharmacia - Ukrainian Pharma Market News Digest. October 2015Upharmacia - Ukrainian Pharma Market News Digest. October 2015
Upharmacia - Ukrainian Pharma Market News Digest. October 2015
 
Convergence Programme of Hungary 2011-2015 pdf download
Convergence Programme of Hungary 2011-2015 pdf downloadConvergence Programme of Hungary 2011-2015 pdf download
Convergence Programme of Hungary 2011-2015 pdf download
 
CASE Network Studies and Analyses 266 - Exchange Rate Regimes and the Nominal...
CASE Network Studies and Analyses 266 - Exchange Rate Regimes and the Nominal...CASE Network Studies and Analyses 266 - Exchange Rate Regimes and the Nominal...
CASE Network Studies and Analyses 266 - Exchange Rate Regimes and the Nominal...
 
Monetary Policies in the US and the Eurozone
Monetary Policies in the US and the EurozoneMonetary Policies in the US and the Eurozone
Monetary Policies in the US and the Eurozone
 
Monthly Newsletter 12/2014
Monthly Newsletter 12/2014Monthly Newsletter 12/2014
Monthly Newsletter 12/2014
 
Hungary's National Reform Programme, pdf, download
Hungary's National Reform Programme, pdf, downloadHungary's National Reform Programme, pdf, download
Hungary's National Reform Programme, pdf, download
 
CASE Network Studies and Analyses 253 - When Should the Central Europeans Joi...
CASE Network Studies and Analyses 253 - When Should the Central Europeans Joi...CASE Network Studies and Analyses 253 - When Should the Central Europeans Joi...
CASE Network Studies and Analyses 253 - When Should the Central Europeans Joi...
 
The Relationship between Macroeconomic Variables and Share Prices: A Case of ...
The Relationship between Macroeconomic Variables and Share Prices: A Case of ...The Relationship between Macroeconomic Variables and Share Prices: A Case of ...
The Relationship between Macroeconomic Variables and Share Prices: A Case of ...
 
Measures of the Output Gap in Turkey: An Empirical Assessment of Selected Met...
Measures of the Output Gap in Turkey: An Empirical Assessment of Selected Met...Measures of the Output Gap in Turkey: An Empirical Assessment of Selected Met...
Measures of the Output Gap in Turkey: An Empirical Assessment of Selected Met...
 
Paper (2)
Paper (2)Paper (2)
Paper (2)
 
CASE Network Studie and Analyses 435 - Two Exercises of Inflation Modelling a...
CASE Network Studie and Analyses 435 - Two Exercises of Inflation Modelling a...CASE Network Studie and Analyses 435 - Two Exercises of Inflation Modelling a...
CASE Network Studie and Analyses 435 - Two Exercises of Inflation Modelling a...
 
Dp12197
Dp12197Dp12197
Dp12197
 
An economic analysis on exchange rate and economic growth in bangladesh
An economic analysis on exchange rate and economic growth in bangladeshAn economic analysis on exchange rate and economic growth in bangladesh
An economic analysis on exchange rate and economic growth in bangladesh
 
132 article text-185-1-10-20210523
132 article text-185-1-10-20210523132 article text-185-1-10-20210523
132 article text-185-1-10-20210523
 
Swedbank Analysis: Competitiveness adjustment in Latvia
Swedbank Analysis: Competitiveness adjustment in LatviaSwedbank Analysis: Competitiveness adjustment in Latvia
Swedbank Analysis: Competitiveness adjustment in Latvia
 

Similar to Convergence of price dynamics assessed in view of Poland’s accession to the euro area focusing on deflation

Fiscal and monetary policy
Fiscal and monetary policyFiscal and monetary policy
Fiscal and monetary policyMonalisa Patel
 
EMU and the Growth and Stability Pact (GSP)
EMU and the Growth and Stability Pact (GSP)EMU and the Growth and Stability Pact (GSP)
EMU and the Growth and Stability Pact (GSP)Nick Chatzipoulidis
 
Vehicle for modernization in trouble. How the eurozone crisis have changed co...
Vehicle for modernization in trouble. How the eurozone crisis have changed co...Vehicle for modernization in trouble. How the eurozone crisis have changed co...
Vehicle for modernization in trouble. How the eurozone crisis have changed co...Rocznik Integracji Europejskiej
 
Una UEM auténtica
Una UEM auténticaUna UEM auténtica
Una UEM auténticaManfredNolte
 
Hacia una UME genuina
Hacia una UME genuinaHacia una UME genuina
Hacia una UME genuinaManfredNolte
 
Breaking the common fate of banks and governments by Daniel Gros and Cinzia A...
Breaking the common fate of banks and governments by Daniel Gros and Cinzia A...Breaking the common fate of banks and governments by Daniel Gros and Cinzia A...
Breaking the common fate of banks and governments by Daniel Gros and Cinzia A...Círculo de Empresarios
 
Declaracion de Mario Draghi (2 de agosto de 2012)
Declaracion de Mario Draghi (2 de agosto de 2012)Declaracion de Mario Draghi (2 de agosto de 2012)
Declaracion de Mario Draghi (2 de agosto de 2012)ManfredNolte
 

Similar to Convergence of price dynamics assessed in view of Poland’s accession to the euro area focusing on deflation (20)

Fiscal and monetary policy
Fiscal and monetary policyFiscal and monetary policy
Fiscal and monetary policy
 
EMU and the Growth and Stability Pact (GSP)
EMU and the Growth and Stability Pact (GSP)EMU and the Growth and Stability Pact (GSP)
EMU and the Growth and Stability Pact (GSP)
 
Vehicle for modernization in trouble. How the eurozone crisis have changed co...
Vehicle for modernization in trouble. How the eurozone crisis have changed co...Vehicle for modernization in trouble. How the eurozone crisis have changed co...
Vehicle for modernization in trouble. How the eurozone crisis have changed co...
 
Ezp wp 17
Ezp wp 17Ezp wp 17
Ezp wp 17
 
CASE Network Studies and Analyses 270 - Nominal and Real Convergence in Alter...
CASE Network Studies and Analyses 270 - Nominal and Real Convergence in Alter...CASE Network Studies and Analyses 270 - Nominal and Real Convergence in Alter...
CASE Network Studies and Analyses 270 - Nominal and Real Convergence in Alter...
 
Una UEM auténtica
Una UEM auténticaUna UEM auténtica
Una UEM auténtica
 
Hacia una UME genuina
Hacia una UME genuinaHacia una UME genuina
Hacia una UME genuina
 
The Economic and Monetary Union: Past, Present and Future
The Economic and Monetary Union: Past, Present and FutureThe Economic and Monetary Union: Past, Present and Future
The Economic and Monetary Union: Past, Present and Future
 
CASE Network Studies and Analyses 443 - Fiscal and Monetary Policy Determinan...
CASE Network Studies and Analyses 443 - Fiscal and Monetary Policy Determinan...CASE Network Studies and Analyses 443 - Fiscal and Monetary Policy Determinan...
CASE Network Studies and Analyses 443 - Fiscal and Monetary Policy Determinan...
 
CASE Network Studies and Analyses 269 - The EMU Enlargement and the Choice of...
CASE Network Studies and Analyses 269 - The EMU Enlargement and the Choice of...CASE Network Studies and Analyses 269 - The EMU Enlargement and the Choice of...
CASE Network Studies and Analyses 269 - The EMU Enlargement and the Choice of...
 
CASE Network Studies and Analyses 290 - A Strategy for EMU Enlargement
CASE Network Studies and Analyses 290 - A Strategy for EMU EnlargementCASE Network Studies and Analyses 290 - A Strategy for EMU Enlargement
CASE Network Studies and Analyses 290 - A Strategy for EMU Enlargement
 
CASE Network Studies and Analyses 294 - Monetary Policy Adjustments on the Fi...
CASE Network Studies and Analyses 294 - Monetary Policy Adjustments on the Fi...CASE Network Studies and Analyses 294 - Monetary Policy Adjustments on the Fi...
CASE Network Studies and Analyses 294 - Monetary Policy Adjustments on the Fi...
 
CASE Network Studies and Analyses 277 - Fiscal Costs of Delaying the EMU Acce...
CASE Network Studies and Analyses 277 - Fiscal Costs of Delaying the EMU Acce...CASE Network Studies and Analyses 277 - Fiscal Costs of Delaying the EMU Acce...
CASE Network Studies and Analyses 277 - Fiscal Costs of Delaying the EMU Acce...
 
CASE Network Studies and Analyses 241 - Inflation and Monetary Policy in Russ...
CASE Network Studies and Analyses 241 - Inflation and Monetary Policy in Russ...CASE Network Studies and Analyses 241 - Inflation and Monetary Policy in Russ...
CASE Network Studies and Analyses 241 - Inflation and Monetary Policy in Russ...
 
Europe without the EU?
Europe without the EU?Europe without the EU?
Europe without the EU?
 
CASE Network Studies and Analyses 466 - Fiscal or Bailout Union: Where Is the...
CASE Network Studies and Analyses 466 - Fiscal or Bailout Union: Where Is the...CASE Network Studies and Analyses 466 - Fiscal or Bailout Union: Where Is the...
CASE Network Studies and Analyses 466 - Fiscal or Bailout Union: Where Is the...
 
Breaking the common fate of banks and governments by Daniel Gros and Cinzia A...
Breaking the common fate of banks and governments by Daniel Gros and Cinzia A...Breaking the common fate of banks and governments by Daniel Gros and Cinzia A...
Breaking the common fate of banks and governments by Daniel Gros and Cinzia A...
 
Declaracion de Mario Draghi (2 de agosto de 2012)
Declaracion de Mario Draghi (2 de agosto de 2012)Declaracion de Mario Draghi (2 de agosto de 2012)
Declaracion de Mario Draghi (2 de agosto de 2012)
 
CASE Network E-briefs 13.2010 - Macroeconomic Surveillance Within the EU
CASE Network E-briefs 13.2010 - Macroeconomic Surveillance Within the EUCASE Network E-briefs 13.2010 - Macroeconomic Surveillance Within the EU
CASE Network E-briefs 13.2010 - Macroeconomic Surveillance Within the EU
 
CASE Network Studies and Analyses 256 - Nominal and Real Convergence in Spain...
CASE Network Studies and Analyses 256 - Nominal and Real Convergence in Spain...CASE Network Studies and Analyses 256 - Nominal and Real Convergence in Spain...
CASE Network Studies and Analyses 256 - Nominal and Real Convergence in Spain...
 

More from Środkowoeuropejskie Studia Polityczne

The activity of the Mamy Głos Foundation in the context of youth political a...
The activity of the Mamy Głos Foundation  in the context of youth political a...The activity of the Mamy Głos Foundation  in the context of youth political a...
The activity of the Mamy Głos Foundation in the context of youth political a...Środkowoeuropejskie Studia Polityczne
 
Impact of Brexit on the status of the English language in the European Union
Impact of Brexit on the status of the English  language in the European UnionImpact of Brexit on the status of the English  language in the European Union
Impact of Brexit on the status of the English language in the European UnionŚrodkowoeuropejskie Studia Polityczne
 
Formation of populism in Spain: towards the explanatory framework of the 15-M...
Formation of populism in Spain: towards the explanatory framework of the 15-M...Formation of populism in Spain: towards the explanatory framework of the 15-M...
Formation of populism in Spain: towards the explanatory framework of the 15-M...Środkowoeuropejskie Studia Polityczne
 
Saturation of the media with conspiracy narratives: content analysis of selec...
Saturation of the media with conspiracy narratives: content analysis of selec...Saturation of the media with conspiracy narratives: content analysis of selec...
Saturation of the media with conspiracy narratives: content analysis of selec...Środkowoeuropejskie Studia Polityczne
 
The Rule of Law and the EU Budget for 2021–2027: More Solidarity or Renouncin...
The Rule of Law and the EU Budget for 2021–2027: More Solidarity or Renouncin...The Rule of Law and the EU Budget for 2021–2027: More Solidarity or Renouncin...
The Rule of Law and the EU Budget for 2021–2027: More Solidarity or Renouncin...Środkowoeuropejskie Studia Polityczne
 
International sports organizations as diplomatic actors. The case of FIFA exe...
International sports organizations as diplomatic actors. The case of FIFA exe...International sports organizations as diplomatic actors. The case of FIFA exe...
International sports organizations as diplomatic actors. The case of FIFA exe...Środkowoeuropejskie Studia Polityczne
 
Civil society as an actor in the political processes of local governance refo...
Civil society as an actor in the political processes of local governance refo...Civil society as an actor in the political processes of local governance refo...
Civil society as an actor in the political processes of local governance refo...Środkowoeuropejskie Studia Polityczne
 
The influence of illiberal democracy on the effectiveness of attempts to cont...
The influence of illiberal democracy on the effectiveness of attempts to cont...The influence of illiberal democracy on the effectiveness of attempts to cont...
The influence of illiberal democracy on the effectiveness of attempts to cont...Środkowoeuropejskie Studia Polityczne
 
Education and information in consumer policy in the Republic of Poland
Education and information in consumer policy  in the Republic of PolandEducation and information in consumer policy  in the Republic of Poland
Education and information in consumer policy in the Republic of PolandŚrodkowoeuropejskie Studia Polityczne
 
Farmland and people as essential resources of Poland in the concepts of Poli...
Farmland and people as essential resources  of Poland in the concepts of Poli...Farmland and people as essential resources  of Poland in the concepts of Poli...
Farmland and people as essential resources of Poland in the concepts of Poli...Środkowoeuropejskie Studia Polityczne
 
The impact of Brexit on the member states’ ability to build blocking coalitio...
The impact of Brexit on the member states’ ability to build blocking coalitio...The impact of Brexit on the member states’ ability to build blocking coalitio...
The impact of Brexit on the member states’ ability to build blocking coalitio...Środkowoeuropejskie Studia Polityczne
 
Dedykowany storytelling – psychologiczne przesłanki perswazyjnej efektywności...
Dedykowany storytelling – psychologiczne przesłanki perswazyjnej efektywności...Dedykowany storytelling – psychologiczne przesłanki perswazyjnej efektywności...
Dedykowany storytelling – psychologiczne przesłanki perswazyjnej efektywności...Środkowoeuropejskie Studia Polityczne
 
Human security, human rights and international law, and interactions between ...
Human security, human rights and international law, and interactions between ...Human security, human rights and international law, and interactions between ...
Human security, human rights and international law, and interactions between ...Środkowoeuropejskie Studia Polityczne
 
Publiczne notowanie akcji jako źródło finansowania małych i średnich przedsię...
Publiczne notowanie akcji jako źródło finansowania małych i średnich przedsię...Publiczne notowanie akcji jako źródło finansowania małych i średnich przedsię...
Publiczne notowanie akcji jako źródło finansowania małych i średnich przedsię...Środkowoeuropejskie Studia Polityczne
 
Polska w strefie euro? Trzy scenariusze i ich prawdopodobne konsekwencje ogól...
Polska w strefie euro? Trzy scenariusze i ich prawdopodobne konsekwencje ogól...Polska w strefie euro? Trzy scenariusze i ich prawdopodobne konsekwencje ogól...
Polska w strefie euro? Trzy scenariusze i ich prawdopodobne konsekwencje ogól...Środkowoeuropejskie Studia Polityczne
 
Próby reformy systemu wyborczego do Rady Najwyższej Ukrainy w okresie przypad...
Próby reformy systemu wyborczego do Rady Najwyższej Ukrainy w okresie przypad...Próby reformy systemu wyborczego do Rady Najwyższej Ukrainy w okresie przypad...
Próby reformy systemu wyborczego do Rady Najwyższej Ukrainy w okresie przypad...Środkowoeuropejskie Studia Polityczne
 
Ustrój samorządu lokalnego w Republice Mołdawii. Ewolucja i stan obecny
Ustrój samorządu lokalnego w Republice Mołdawii. Ewolucja i stan obecnyUstrój samorządu lokalnego w Republice Mołdawii. Ewolucja i stan obecny
Ustrój samorządu lokalnego w Republice Mołdawii. Ewolucja i stan obecnyŚrodkowoeuropejskie Studia Polityczne
 

More from Środkowoeuropejskie Studia Polityczne (20)

The activity of the Mamy Głos Foundation in the context of youth political a...
The activity of the Mamy Głos Foundation  in the context of youth political a...The activity of the Mamy Głos Foundation  in the context of youth political a...
The activity of the Mamy Głos Foundation in the context of youth political a...
 
Impact of Brexit on the status of the English language in the European Union
Impact of Brexit on the status of the English  language in the European UnionImpact of Brexit on the status of the English  language in the European Union
Impact of Brexit on the status of the English language in the European Union
 
Formation of populism in Spain: towards the explanatory framework of the 15-M...
Formation of populism in Spain: towards the explanatory framework of the 15-M...Formation of populism in Spain: towards the explanatory framework of the 15-M...
Formation of populism in Spain: towards the explanatory framework of the 15-M...
 
Non-military dimension of the hybrid war in Ukraine
Non-military dimension of the hybrid war  in UkraineNon-military dimension of the hybrid war  in Ukraine
Non-military dimension of the hybrid war in Ukraine
 
Saturation of the media with conspiracy narratives: content analysis of selec...
Saturation of the media with conspiracy narratives: content analysis of selec...Saturation of the media with conspiracy narratives: content analysis of selec...
Saturation of the media with conspiracy narratives: content analysis of selec...
 
Promotion of regional and traditional products
Promotion of regional and traditional productsPromotion of regional and traditional products
Promotion of regional and traditional products
 
The Rule of Law and the EU Budget for 2021–2027: More Solidarity or Renouncin...
The Rule of Law and the EU Budget for 2021–2027: More Solidarity or Renouncin...The Rule of Law and the EU Budget for 2021–2027: More Solidarity or Renouncin...
The Rule of Law and the EU Budget for 2021–2027: More Solidarity or Renouncin...
 
International sports organizations as diplomatic actors. The case of FIFA exe...
International sports organizations as diplomatic actors. The case of FIFA exe...International sports organizations as diplomatic actors. The case of FIFA exe...
International sports organizations as diplomatic actors. The case of FIFA exe...
 
Civil society as an actor in the political processes of local governance refo...
Civil society as an actor in the political processes of local governance refo...Civil society as an actor in the political processes of local governance refo...
Civil society as an actor in the political processes of local governance refo...
 
The influence of illiberal democracy on the effectiveness of attempts to cont...
The influence of illiberal democracy on the effectiveness of attempts to cont...The influence of illiberal democracy on the effectiveness of attempts to cont...
The influence of illiberal democracy on the effectiveness of attempts to cont...
 
Education and information in consumer policy in the Republic of Poland
Education and information in consumer policy  in the Republic of PolandEducation and information in consumer policy  in the Republic of Poland
Education and information in consumer policy in the Republic of Poland
 
Farmland and people as essential resources of Poland in the concepts of Poli...
Farmland and people as essential resources  of Poland in the concepts of Poli...Farmland and people as essential resources  of Poland in the concepts of Poli...
Farmland and people as essential resources of Poland in the concepts of Poli...
 
The impact of Brexit on the member states’ ability to build blocking coalitio...
The impact of Brexit on the member states’ ability to build blocking coalitio...The impact of Brexit on the member states’ ability to build blocking coalitio...
The impact of Brexit on the member states’ ability to build blocking coalitio...
 
Dedykowany storytelling – psychologiczne przesłanki perswazyjnej efektywności...
Dedykowany storytelling – psychologiczne przesłanki perswazyjnej efektywności...Dedykowany storytelling – psychologiczne przesłanki perswazyjnej efektywności...
Dedykowany storytelling – psychologiczne przesłanki perswazyjnej efektywności...
 
Human security, human rights and international law, and interactions between ...
Human security, human rights and international law, and interactions between ...Human security, human rights and international law, and interactions between ...
Human security, human rights and international law, and interactions between ...
 
Publiczne notowanie akcji jako źródło finansowania małych i średnich przedsię...
Publiczne notowanie akcji jako źródło finansowania małych i średnich przedsię...Publiczne notowanie akcji jako źródło finansowania małych i średnich przedsię...
Publiczne notowanie akcji jako źródło finansowania małych i średnich przedsię...
 
Polska w strefie euro? Trzy scenariusze i ich prawdopodobne konsekwencje ogól...
Polska w strefie euro? Trzy scenariusze i ich prawdopodobne konsekwencje ogól...Polska w strefie euro? Trzy scenariusze i ich prawdopodobne konsekwencje ogól...
Polska w strefie euro? Trzy scenariusze i ich prawdopodobne konsekwencje ogól...
 
Trauma transformacji w Europie Środkowo-Wschodniej
Trauma transformacji w Europie Środkowo-WschodniejTrauma transformacji w Europie Środkowo-Wschodniej
Trauma transformacji w Europie Środkowo-Wschodniej
 
Próby reformy systemu wyborczego do Rady Najwyższej Ukrainy w okresie przypad...
Próby reformy systemu wyborczego do Rady Najwyższej Ukrainy w okresie przypad...Próby reformy systemu wyborczego do Rady Najwyższej Ukrainy w okresie przypad...
Próby reformy systemu wyborczego do Rady Najwyższej Ukrainy w okresie przypad...
 
Ustrój samorządu lokalnego w Republice Mołdawii. Ewolucja i stan obecny
Ustrój samorządu lokalnego w Republice Mołdawii. Ewolucja i stan obecnyUstrój samorządu lokalnego w Republice Mołdawii. Ewolucja i stan obecny
Ustrój samorządu lokalnego w Republice Mołdawii. Ewolucja i stan obecny
 

Recently uploaded

WhatsApp 📞 8448380779 ✅Call Girls In Chaura Sector 22 ( Noida)
WhatsApp 📞 8448380779 ✅Call Girls In Chaura Sector 22 ( Noida)WhatsApp 📞 8448380779 ✅Call Girls In Chaura Sector 22 ( Noida)
WhatsApp 📞 8448380779 ✅Call Girls In Chaura Sector 22 ( Noida)Delhi Call girls
 
How Europe Underdeveloped Africa_walter.pdf
How Europe Underdeveloped Africa_walter.pdfHow Europe Underdeveloped Africa_walter.pdf
How Europe Underdeveloped Africa_walter.pdfLorenzo Lemes
 
Powerful Love Spells in Phoenix, AZ (310) 882-6330 Bring Back Lost Lover
Powerful Love Spells in Phoenix, AZ (310) 882-6330 Bring Back Lost LoverPowerful Love Spells in Phoenix, AZ (310) 882-6330 Bring Back Lost Lover
Powerful Love Spells in Phoenix, AZ (310) 882-6330 Bring Back Lost LoverPsychicRuben LoveSpells
 
HARNESSING AI FOR ENHANCED MEDIA ANALYSIS A CASE STUDY ON CHATGPT AT DRONE EM...
HARNESSING AI FOR ENHANCED MEDIA ANALYSIS A CASE STUDY ON CHATGPT AT DRONE EM...HARNESSING AI FOR ENHANCED MEDIA ANALYSIS A CASE STUDY ON CHATGPT AT DRONE EM...
HARNESSING AI FOR ENHANCED MEDIA ANALYSIS A CASE STUDY ON CHATGPT AT DRONE EM...Ismail Fahmi
 
30042024_First India Newspaper Jaipur.pdf
30042024_First India Newspaper Jaipur.pdf30042024_First India Newspaper Jaipur.pdf
30042024_First India Newspaper Jaipur.pdfFIRST INDIA
 
AI as Research Assistant: Upscaling Content Analysis to Identify Patterns of ...
AI as Research Assistant: Upscaling Content Analysis to Identify Patterns of ...AI as Research Assistant: Upscaling Content Analysis to Identify Patterns of ...
AI as Research Assistant: Upscaling Content Analysis to Identify Patterns of ...Axel Bruns
 
2024 04 03 AZ GOP LD4 Gen Meeting Minutes FINAL.docx
2024 04 03 AZ GOP LD4 Gen Meeting Minutes FINAL.docx2024 04 03 AZ GOP LD4 Gen Meeting Minutes FINAL.docx
2024 04 03 AZ GOP LD4 Gen Meeting Minutes FINAL.docxkfjstone13
 
Lorenzo D'Emidio_Lavoro sullaNorth Korea .pptx
Lorenzo D'Emidio_Lavoro sullaNorth Korea .pptxLorenzo D'Emidio_Lavoro sullaNorth Korea .pptx
Lorenzo D'Emidio_Lavoro sullaNorth Korea .pptxlorenzodemidio01
 
TDP As the Party of Hope For AP Youth Under N Chandrababu Naidu’s Leadership
TDP As the Party of Hope For AP Youth Under N Chandrababu Naidu’s LeadershipTDP As the Party of Hope For AP Youth Under N Chandrababu Naidu’s Leadership
TDP As the Party of Hope For AP Youth Under N Chandrababu Naidu’s Leadershipanjanibaddipudi1
 
Minto-Morley Reforms 1909 (constitution).pptx
Minto-Morley Reforms 1909 (constitution).pptxMinto-Morley Reforms 1909 (constitution).pptx
Minto-Morley Reforms 1909 (constitution).pptxAwaiskhalid96
 
BDSM⚡Call Girls in Greater Noida Escorts >༒8448380779 Escort Service
BDSM⚡Call Girls in Greater Noida Escorts >༒8448380779 Escort ServiceBDSM⚡Call Girls in Greater Noida Escorts >༒8448380779 Escort Service
BDSM⚡Call Girls in Greater Noida Escorts >༒8448380779 Escort ServiceDelhi Call girls
 
26042024_First India Newspaper Jaipur.pdf
26042024_First India Newspaper Jaipur.pdf26042024_First India Newspaper Jaipur.pdf
26042024_First India Newspaper Jaipur.pdfFIRST INDIA
 
BDSM⚡Call Girls in Sector 135 Noida Escorts >༒8448380779 Escort Service
BDSM⚡Call Girls in Sector 135 Noida Escorts >༒8448380779 Escort ServiceBDSM⚡Call Girls in Sector 135 Noida Escorts >༒8448380779 Escort Service
BDSM⚡Call Girls in Sector 135 Noida Escorts >༒8448380779 Escort ServiceDelhi Call girls
 
Enjoy Night⚡Call Girls Rajokri Delhi >༒8448380779 Escort Service
Enjoy Night⚡Call Girls Rajokri Delhi >༒8448380779 Escort ServiceEnjoy Night⚡Call Girls Rajokri Delhi >༒8448380779 Escort Service
Enjoy Night⚡Call Girls Rajokri Delhi >༒8448380779 Escort ServiceDelhi Call girls
 
Pakistan PMLN Election Manifesto 2024.pdf
Pakistan PMLN Election Manifesto 2024.pdfPakistan PMLN Election Manifesto 2024.pdf
Pakistan PMLN Election Manifesto 2024.pdfFahimUddin61
 
Enjoy Night⚡Call Girls Iffco Chowk Gurgaon >༒8448380779 Escort Service
Enjoy Night⚡Call Girls Iffco Chowk Gurgaon >༒8448380779 Escort ServiceEnjoy Night⚡Call Girls Iffco Chowk Gurgaon >༒8448380779 Escort Service
Enjoy Night⚡Call Girls Iffco Chowk Gurgaon >༒8448380779 Escort ServiceDelhi Call girls
 
BDSM⚡Call Girls in Sector 143 Noida Escorts >༒8448380779 Escort Service
BDSM⚡Call Girls in Sector 143 Noida Escorts >༒8448380779 Escort ServiceBDSM⚡Call Girls in Sector 143 Noida Escorts >༒8448380779 Escort Service
BDSM⚡Call Girls in Sector 143 Noida Escorts >༒8448380779 Escort ServiceDelhi Call girls
 
Gujarat-SEBCs.pdf pfpkoopapriorjfperjreie
Gujarat-SEBCs.pdf pfpkoopapriorjfperjreieGujarat-SEBCs.pdf pfpkoopapriorjfperjreie
Gujarat-SEBCs.pdf pfpkoopapriorjfperjreiebhavenpr
 
Israel Palestine Conflict, The issue and historical context!
Israel Palestine Conflict, The issue and historical context!Israel Palestine Conflict, The issue and historical context!
Israel Palestine Conflict, The issue and historical context!Krish109503
 
Nurturing Families, Empowering Lives: TDP's Vision for Family Welfare in Andh...
Nurturing Families, Empowering Lives: TDP's Vision for Family Welfare in Andh...Nurturing Families, Empowering Lives: TDP's Vision for Family Welfare in Andh...
Nurturing Families, Empowering Lives: TDP's Vision for Family Welfare in Andh...narsireddynannuri1
 

Recently uploaded (20)

WhatsApp 📞 8448380779 ✅Call Girls In Chaura Sector 22 ( Noida)
WhatsApp 📞 8448380779 ✅Call Girls In Chaura Sector 22 ( Noida)WhatsApp 📞 8448380779 ✅Call Girls In Chaura Sector 22 ( Noida)
WhatsApp 📞 8448380779 ✅Call Girls In Chaura Sector 22 ( Noida)
 
How Europe Underdeveloped Africa_walter.pdf
How Europe Underdeveloped Africa_walter.pdfHow Europe Underdeveloped Africa_walter.pdf
How Europe Underdeveloped Africa_walter.pdf
 
Powerful Love Spells in Phoenix, AZ (310) 882-6330 Bring Back Lost Lover
Powerful Love Spells in Phoenix, AZ (310) 882-6330 Bring Back Lost LoverPowerful Love Spells in Phoenix, AZ (310) 882-6330 Bring Back Lost Lover
Powerful Love Spells in Phoenix, AZ (310) 882-6330 Bring Back Lost Lover
 
HARNESSING AI FOR ENHANCED MEDIA ANALYSIS A CASE STUDY ON CHATGPT AT DRONE EM...
HARNESSING AI FOR ENHANCED MEDIA ANALYSIS A CASE STUDY ON CHATGPT AT DRONE EM...HARNESSING AI FOR ENHANCED MEDIA ANALYSIS A CASE STUDY ON CHATGPT AT DRONE EM...
HARNESSING AI FOR ENHANCED MEDIA ANALYSIS A CASE STUDY ON CHATGPT AT DRONE EM...
 
30042024_First India Newspaper Jaipur.pdf
30042024_First India Newspaper Jaipur.pdf30042024_First India Newspaper Jaipur.pdf
30042024_First India Newspaper Jaipur.pdf
 
AI as Research Assistant: Upscaling Content Analysis to Identify Patterns of ...
AI as Research Assistant: Upscaling Content Analysis to Identify Patterns of ...AI as Research Assistant: Upscaling Content Analysis to Identify Patterns of ...
AI as Research Assistant: Upscaling Content Analysis to Identify Patterns of ...
 
2024 04 03 AZ GOP LD4 Gen Meeting Minutes FINAL.docx
2024 04 03 AZ GOP LD4 Gen Meeting Minutes FINAL.docx2024 04 03 AZ GOP LD4 Gen Meeting Minutes FINAL.docx
2024 04 03 AZ GOP LD4 Gen Meeting Minutes FINAL.docx
 
Lorenzo D'Emidio_Lavoro sullaNorth Korea .pptx
Lorenzo D'Emidio_Lavoro sullaNorth Korea .pptxLorenzo D'Emidio_Lavoro sullaNorth Korea .pptx
Lorenzo D'Emidio_Lavoro sullaNorth Korea .pptx
 
TDP As the Party of Hope For AP Youth Under N Chandrababu Naidu’s Leadership
TDP As the Party of Hope For AP Youth Under N Chandrababu Naidu’s LeadershipTDP As the Party of Hope For AP Youth Under N Chandrababu Naidu’s Leadership
TDP As the Party of Hope For AP Youth Under N Chandrababu Naidu’s Leadership
 
Minto-Morley Reforms 1909 (constitution).pptx
Minto-Morley Reforms 1909 (constitution).pptxMinto-Morley Reforms 1909 (constitution).pptx
Minto-Morley Reforms 1909 (constitution).pptx
 
BDSM⚡Call Girls in Greater Noida Escorts >༒8448380779 Escort Service
BDSM⚡Call Girls in Greater Noida Escorts >༒8448380779 Escort ServiceBDSM⚡Call Girls in Greater Noida Escorts >༒8448380779 Escort Service
BDSM⚡Call Girls in Greater Noida Escorts >༒8448380779 Escort Service
 
26042024_First India Newspaper Jaipur.pdf
26042024_First India Newspaper Jaipur.pdf26042024_First India Newspaper Jaipur.pdf
26042024_First India Newspaper Jaipur.pdf
 
BDSM⚡Call Girls in Sector 135 Noida Escorts >༒8448380779 Escort Service
BDSM⚡Call Girls in Sector 135 Noida Escorts >༒8448380779 Escort ServiceBDSM⚡Call Girls in Sector 135 Noida Escorts >༒8448380779 Escort Service
BDSM⚡Call Girls in Sector 135 Noida Escorts >༒8448380779 Escort Service
 
Enjoy Night⚡Call Girls Rajokri Delhi >༒8448380779 Escort Service
Enjoy Night⚡Call Girls Rajokri Delhi >༒8448380779 Escort ServiceEnjoy Night⚡Call Girls Rajokri Delhi >༒8448380779 Escort Service
Enjoy Night⚡Call Girls Rajokri Delhi >༒8448380779 Escort Service
 
Pakistan PMLN Election Manifesto 2024.pdf
Pakistan PMLN Election Manifesto 2024.pdfPakistan PMLN Election Manifesto 2024.pdf
Pakistan PMLN Election Manifesto 2024.pdf
 
Enjoy Night⚡Call Girls Iffco Chowk Gurgaon >༒8448380779 Escort Service
Enjoy Night⚡Call Girls Iffco Chowk Gurgaon >༒8448380779 Escort ServiceEnjoy Night⚡Call Girls Iffco Chowk Gurgaon >༒8448380779 Escort Service
Enjoy Night⚡Call Girls Iffco Chowk Gurgaon >༒8448380779 Escort Service
 
BDSM⚡Call Girls in Sector 143 Noida Escorts >༒8448380779 Escort Service
BDSM⚡Call Girls in Sector 143 Noida Escorts >༒8448380779 Escort ServiceBDSM⚡Call Girls in Sector 143 Noida Escorts >༒8448380779 Escort Service
BDSM⚡Call Girls in Sector 143 Noida Escorts >༒8448380779 Escort Service
 
Gujarat-SEBCs.pdf pfpkoopapriorjfperjreie
Gujarat-SEBCs.pdf pfpkoopapriorjfperjreieGujarat-SEBCs.pdf pfpkoopapriorjfperjreie
Gujarat-SEBCs.pdf pfpkoopapriorjfperjreie
 
Israel Palestine Conflict, The issue and historical context!
Israel Palestine Conflict, The issue and historical context!Israel Palestine Conflict, The issue and historical context!
Israel Palestine Conflict, The issue and historical context!
 
Nurturing Families, Empowering Lives: TDP's Vision for Family Welfare in Andh...
Nurturing Families, Empowering Lives: TDP's Vision for Family Welfare in Andh...Nurturing Families, Empowering Lives: TDP's Vision for Family Welfare in Andh...
Nurturing Families, Empowering Lives: TDP's Vision for Family Welfare in Andh...
 

Convergence of price dynamics assessed in view of Poland’s accession to the euro area focusing on deflation

  • 1. DOI 10.14746/ssp.2018.3.7 Paweł Błaszczyk Poznań University of Economics and Business Łukasz Fojutowski Collegium Da Vinci Convergence of price dynamics assessed in view of Poland’s accession to the euro area focusing on deflation Abstract: The primary aim of this study was to assess the degree of Poland’s con- vergence in terms of price stability, both at the stage of the country’s candidacy to the euro area and in relation to the euro convergence criteria (the so-called Maastricht criteria), and in the broader context of the ECB’s unified monetary policy. The time frame for this study covers the period of 2004–2017. The starting point marks Po- land’s accession to the EU, which is a pre-requisite for application to access the euro area. The closing time was chosen due to the availability of data, mainly from the Eu- rostat database. This was studied in view of the critical analysis of methodology and the method used to establish the Maastricht criterion for the dynamics of the general price level. The methodology of determining the inflation criterion is flawed and not matched to today’s economic conditions, including the definition of price stability ap- plied in the practice of central banking, as well as in the context of the phenomenon of deflation commonly occurring in the last decade. As a consequence, the value of the criterion for a candidate country may turn out to be very low, and may unjustifiably increase the costs of accession to the euro area, also in the long-term perspective. Such a problem should be taken into account in the discussion on Poland’s accession to the euro area, which is usually of a political, as well as social and economic nature. This economic aspect, however, should be key in practice. Key words: deflation, economic integration, euro area, monetary policy, price stability Introduction European integration processes lasting many decades now have been strongly connected with the process of convergence, understood as the process of economies becoming increasingly similar, which leads to their convergence. On the one hand, convergence is a pre-condition for
  • 2. 100 Paweł Błaszczyk, Łukasz Fojutowski ŚSP 3 ’18 integration, while on the other hand it is its objective, which is to con- tribute to the socio-economic growth and development of united Europe. When we consider the European Union (EU) and the euro area (EA) as a certain stage in the overall integration process (Molle, 2000, part I ff.), which may be termed as an incomplete economic and monetary union (De Grauwe, 2003, pp. 107–140; Zwierzchlewski, 2015, Chapter 1), we need to stress that certain conditions need to be met to participate, such as those related to economic convergence, both in terms of membership of the EU and next also of the EA. In turn, accession to such associations may promote convergence, as indicated e.g. by the structure and scale of the EU budget. Fiscal policy in Europe is primarily executed at the national level (both central and local governments), while the EU budget is mainly to ensure redistribution in order to enhance socio-economic co- hesion within more specific areas (see EU budget structure). However, its excessive growth and incorporation of a wider range of fiscal func- tions outside the area of convergence are considered disadvantageous, as evidenced by the limit for its volume established at 1.24% of the GDP of member countries.1 Also in the monetary (currency) aspect, convergence is inseparably associated with European integration. In this sense, it refers first of all to the Maastricht criteria as pre-conditions for accession to the euro area. However, these should not be considered solely as boundary conditions to be met in order to access the European Monetary Union, but rather as a completion and verification of the conclusion for the convergence proc- ess in relation to the applicant country. This study is focused on the cri- terion related to price stability and more broadly speaking – to the entire convergence process in this area in view of accession and membership in the Monetary Union (compare Ochryniuk, Rogut, 2010). This is connect- ed with serious problems, not only for the euro area candidate country which has to meet the requirement not only before, but also after acces- sion; a problem lies also in the methodology of establishing the criterion itself. The above-mentioned problems discussed within this study have a significant impact on the balance of costs and benefits connected with accession to the zone of the common European currency (De Grauwe, 2003, Chapters 1–4). Divergence in the dynamics of the general price level not only hinders accession to the euro area and makes it more costly, but also leads to incompatibility with the EU’s unified monetary policy of 1   For more on the EU budget and its rules see: e.g. Zombirt (2008, pp. 455–489).
  • 3. ŚSP 3 ’18 Convergence of price dynamics assessed in view of Poland’s... 101 the European Central Bank (ECB) and generates resulting participation costs (Błaszczyk, 2016). This is a particularly important issue from the point of view of the chal- lenges of economic policy in Poland in the face of accession to the euro area. An economic analysis of the balance of costs and benefits should be the basis for the discussion on making the final political decision on the date of accession – a decision which, however, is not only political and economic, but also social in nature.2 Our decision-makers should con- sider a number of factors regarding both the pre-accession process and the conditions of belonging to the euro area, particularly in the face of the crisis situations in European economic and monetary union in the last decade (Walkowski, 2012). It should be emphasized that this article focuses mainly on economic and monetary aspects of convergence with the euro area. In this context, the primary aim of this paper is to assess the degree of Poland’s convergence in terms of price stability, both at the stage of our candidacy to the euro area and in relation to the Maastricht criteria, and in the broader context of the ECB’s unified monetary policy. These aspects were studied in relation to the critical analysis of the methodology and the method used to establish the Maastricht criterion for the dynamics of the general price level. The time frame for the study covers the period of 2004–2017. The starting point marks Poland’s accession to the EU, which is a pre-requisite for the application to access the euro area. The closing time point results from the availability of data, mainly in relation to the Eurostat database. This study is composed of two basic parts. One concerns the method- ology for the Maastricht inflation criterion.3 A critical analysis of it was performed, indicating its incompatibility with current economic condi- tions, particularly in view of the definitions of price stability applied in central banking practice, as well as the deflation phenomena observed in the last decade. The paper presents the phenomena which should be con- 2   For a broad look at the balance of costs and benefits of Poland’s accession to the euro area against the background of the economic convergence process see: e.g. NBP (2009), Wójcik (2008), Pronobis (2008), Szeląg (1998). 3   In view of the potential inclusion of reference countries experiencing deflation in the establishment of the criterion, the term inflation criterion is incorrect. It should rather be referred to as price stability or dynamics of the general price level. However, in view of common use it was decided also to use the phrase inflation criterion in this study.
  • 4. 102 Paweł Błaszczyk, Łukasz Fojutowski ŚSP 3 ’18 sidered in the adaptation of the methodology, e.g. in the context of Mon- etary Union, to be applied in the regional variation in the dynamics of the general price level. In the following part, several variants for changes in the methodology of the Maastricht inflation criterion are presented, and then in this context nominal convergence in Poland is assessed. 1. Price stability and the Maastricht inflation criterion The Maastricht inflation criterion is one of the five primary nominal pre-conditions for accession to the EA. The other criteria concern long- term interest rates and government debt, as well as exchange rates. The idea underlying these criteria is to achieve and maintain a specific degree of convergence which will determine the balance of costs and benefits of EAmembership. Economic convergence of the countries promotes the in- creased effectiveness and efficiency of the ECB’s unified monetary policy. Countries which deviate from the EA average may incur losses resulting from the incompatibility of the unified policy with domestic economic conditions, particularly the dynamics of the general price level. This may result in one of the most often stressed threats for accession to the EA, i.e. loss of autonomy in monetary and exchange rate policies. In the case of monetary divergence, the unified ECB instruments, established based on the average parameters for EA and considering a 2% inflation target, may be unsuitable for countries unable to meet the fixed parameters. For example, in countries with the lowest inflation rates, or even deflation, the EU monetary policy would become too restrictive (due to the high real rate), having a negative effect on employment rates and domestic product, while in countries with higher inflation rates it would be too expansive (due to the low real rate), promoting further increases in inflation, instead of stabilizing it at the level of the EA target. As a result, on the one hand the situation on the labor market would deteriorate, while on the other hand inflation trends would accelerate, e.g. in relation to the expected inflation rate. In contrast, if convergence is properly executed, taking into consideration long-term forecasts, and not only in view of meeting the Maastricht criteria, the above-mentioned autonomy of national policies will never be needed (or will only be needed rarely) and the unified ECB policy will prove sufficient. The idea of the inflation criterion for convergence is thus particularly positive in the context of European integration, a process currently ob- served at the level of economic and monetary policies, having already covered the level of markets both for goods and services and factors of production, including e.g. the stages of the free trade zone, customs union
  • 5. ŚSP 3 ’18 Convergence of price dynamics assessed in view of Poland’s... 103 or the common market (Molle, 2000). However, doubts may be raised on the one hand by the methodology used to establish this criterion4 and on the other hand – by its implementation by the candidate countries and their EA counterparts. In relation to the concept of reaching a high level of sustainable con- vergence within the euro area, the Treaty stipulates that one of the condi- tions is “the achievement of a high degree of price stability; this will be apparent from a rate of inflation which is close to that of, at most, the three best performing Member States in terms of price stability” (Article 140 of the Treaty on the Functioning of the European Union). According to Ar- ticle 1 of the Protocol on the Convergence Criteria the level of inflation in a given country within the year preceding the analysis may not exceed the inflation rates in the three EU states with the most stable price levels expressed in terms of HICP (Harmonised Index of Consumer Prices) by more than 1.5 pp. The method of identifying reference countries raises doubts. It is difficult to clearly define the term “best performing Member States in terms of price stability.” Price stability can be an ambiguous concept (Błaszczyk, 2010), particularly in relation to the quantitative as- pect. Apart from the other aspects of the definition of price stability, par- ticularly disregarding its potential measurement through the price level path, and assuming the rate of change in the general price level, its target value needs to be considered (Błaszczyk, 2010). The European Commission is not consistent in the identification of reference states, and thus in defining “the best performance in terms of price stability.” Generally, countries with the lowest mean annual rate of inflation are selected. A problem appeared in the case of zero and nega- tive dynamics of the general price level. For example, in 2004, in the Reports on Convergence the European Committee decided to eliminate Lithuania from the group of reference countries, which at that time was experiencing deflation measured using HICP. However, already in 2010, with several EU countries reporting deflation (Ireland, Portugal, Estonia, Belgium, Spain) the European Commission arbitrarily decided only to eliminate Ireland, with the highest deflation rate, from the reference state group. In the following years, when deflation was recorded worldwide, in relation to decreasing prices of raw materials on the world markets, including oil, countries with deflation were not rejected. 4   An interesting collection of studies on the validity of the definition of price stability as well as the entire ECB monetary policy strategy is available from the ECB (2003).
  • 6. 104 Paweł Błaszczyk, Łukasz Fojutowski ŚSP 3 ’18 In such a situation, apart from the fact that the investigated criterion is relative in character and its variability may cause uncertainty regarding an EA candidate country, it may prove to be undesirably low, including values close to zero, or even hypothetically negative. We may thus ques- tion whether it is justified to meet such a ‘reduced’ criterion, due to the potential forcing of a considerable restriction of economic policy and re- lated unjustified high costs. For example, a situation may arise in which a candidate country would have to reduce an inflation level which under normal conditions would be considered advantageous and optimal (e.g. 2.5%), to values considered harmful (close, equal to or below zero), since this is indicated by the current situation in the euro area, specifically in relation to only the three countries with the lowest price dynamics. Sur- prisingly, the value of the criterion may be incompatible with the ECB’s definition of price stability, indicating 2% inflation, while the idea behind the implementation of this criterion is to achieve convergence with the euro area and adaptation to the ‘average’ unified ECB policy, which de- termines the long-term benefits from EAmembership. Why is the value of the criterion to be determined by countries with the lowest price dynamics (irrespective of the addition of 1.5 pp to the mean price dynamics in those countries) and not, for example, those with medium dynamics, since the ECB policy refers mainly to such a parameter? Thus, it is necessary to discuss the redefinition of the price stability criterion, or at least to clearly specify the concept of countries with the greatest price stability. To do this, the notion of price stability needs to be analyzed. It would seem that price stability is equivalent to zero inflation. How- ever, hypothetically price stability may be defined in terms of a negative, zero or positive rate of change in the general price level. Each solution has its advantages and disadvantages; however, both empirical studies and central banking practice definitely indicate a positive inflation target. The value most commonly applied by countries using the direct inflation target- ing strategy, assuming price stability as a primary objective, and specified explicitly in the form of the inflation target falls within the range of 2–3% (Błaszczyk, 2010). For example, inflation targets of the oldest central banks worldwide, i.e. Sveriges Riksbank and the Bank of England, amount to 2%, similarly as it is for the Federal Reserve System (since 2012) and the Bank of Japan (since 2013). At present, the ECB defines price stability as infla- tion below 2%, but close to that value, whereas for the National Bank of Poland NBP it is 2.5% +/– 1 pp. Discussions on price stability indicate that the reference countries being best performers in terms of price stability in
  • 7. ŚSP 3 ’18 Convergence of price dynamics assessed in view of Poland’s... 105 relation to the Maastricht criterion should have this specified inflation level. Taking into consideration the EU countries, and at the same time candidate or EA countries, the term “the greatest price stability” should refer to the ECB target, i.e. approx. 2% or slightly below that value, such as 1.5–2% and possibly also above, considering the symmetry of the inflation target. Thus, the candidate countries would strive to attain a target, which will later be binding within the ECB’s unified monetary policy. From the point of view of both the society and the economy, many factors indicate the advisability of establishing a positive (non-zero and non-negative) inflation target reflecting the optimal dynamics of the gen- eral price level. They include e.g.: downward nominal wage rigidity (Akerlof, Dickens, Perry, 1996, pp.–– 1–59; Akerlof, Dickens, Perry, 2000; Keynes, 2003, pp. 231–244; Kwiatkowski, 2002, p. 105; Wojtyna, 2004, p. 202; for Japan: Kimura, Ueda, 1997; for the USA: Lebow, Saks, Wilson, 2003; for Switzer- land: Fehr, Goette, 2000; for Germany: Knoppik, Beissinger, 2001: for Sweden: Ekberg, 2002; for Great Britain: Nickell, Quintini, 2003, and for Italy: Devicienti, 2004); nominal interest rate floor (Wojtyna, 2001; IMF, 1999, p. 101; Sven-–– sson, 2000, pp. 27–28, 41); risk of deflation (Kumar, Baig, Decressin, Faulkner-MacDonagh,–– Feyzioglu, 2003; Kilian, Manganelli, 2007, pp. 561–588); overestimation of actual dynamics of the general price level (mainly–– CPI and similar measures) (Social Security Administration, 1996; Friedman, 2002, pp. 89–90, Wynne, Rodriguez-Palenzuela, 2002); seigniorage (Cukrowski, 2001);–– regional variation in dynamics of the general price level in the Mon-–– etary Union (Weber, Beck, 2005; Wójcik, 2008, pp. 106–142; Alda- soro, Zdarek 2009; Błaszczyk, 2014; Błaszczyk, 2016). In order to present these aspects in terms of the identification of the inflation target we may use formula 1. Π* = ΠE + max {ΠDNWR , ΠDNIRB , ΠDT , ΠRVPD ...} (1) where: Π* – value of the inflation target, ΠE – value of error for inflation measurement, ΠDNWR – inflation rate considering downward nominal wage rigidity, ΠDNIRB – inflation rate constituting downward bound against nominal in- terest rate floor,
  • 8. 106 Paweł Błaszczyk, Łukasz Fojutowski ŚSP 3 ’18 ΠDT – inflation rate hedging against other deflation threats, e.g. liquidity trap or deflation spiral, ΠRVPD – inflation rate considering regional variation in price dynamics within the Monetary Union. The beginning of the formula needs to include an error for the meas- ured dynamics in the general price level, above all overestimation. Preferably, the errors should be eliminated, rather than included in the target value. Thus, the factor differs from the others indicated in the procedure, since their incorporation is, in reality, required to attain the target inflation rate. The other phenomena are substitutionary in relation to one another, i.e. the maximum inflation value resulting from each of them provides a buffer against all the others. For this reason, this value is added to the measurement error. The formula ends with an ellipsis to indicate that other factors, more or less directly associated with defla- tion conditions, may be included, e.g. inflation rate generated by the profits from seigniorage. In view of current monetary policy, including the independence of central banks, this argument is increasingly losing importance, particularly in relation to Monetary Union. Estimates for individual factors in this formula will differ for individual countries/ unions, and thus it is impossible to indicate a universal optimal value of inflation target. In the case of monetary union, such as in the euro area, an additional factor will be connected with the regional diversity in the dynamics of the general price level. This results first of all from the asymmetry of shocks affecting various countries, and differences in the mechanisms of their transmission. The reasons may stem from the regulations of the product and labor markets (Moretti, 2014). In this context we should also stress the role of the Harrod-Balassa-Samuelson effect (H-B-S). It affects mainly those countries which are characterized by a relatively high growth rate in the production efficiency of exchangeable goods. This increase leads indirectly to a real, absorbable appreciation of cur- rency, or nominal appreciation, or through a greater growth rate for do- mestic prices. According to the H-B-S model, this mechanism consists of a rapid growth in productivity in the exchangeable goods sector, lead- ing to an increase in wages in that sector. This is because prices for those goods are exogenous, and are determined on the world market. Since we are dealing with perfect capital mobility between the sectors of exchangeable and non-exchangeable goods, wages in the latter sec- tor will also increase. However, the growth rate in productivity is lower.
  • 9. ŚSP 3 ’18 Convergence of price dynamics assessed in view of Poland’s... 107 The increase in wages will be reflected in the growth of prices in the non-exchangeable goods sector and as a consequence – in an increase in the general price level. Finally, countries with a high productivity growth rate (first of all small, open emerging economies) will potentially have higher inflation in comparison to countries with a lower growth rate, but not a lower level of productivity (primarily more developed countries) (Chmielewski, 2003). Inflation resulting from the H-B-S effect may be considered ‘good.’ This may be termed as resulting from a reduced distance between more and less developed economies. For this reason, it is not advisable to take ac- tions to reduce such inflation. It should be first included in the ECB infla- tion target, and secondly it needs to be incorporated in the methodology for the Maastricht criterion. An empirical assessment of regional differences in the general price level dynamics in the euro area, as compared to that in the entire EU in the years of 2004–2017, is presented in Fig. 1. The data given in the top section of Fig. 1 refer to the maximum, minimum and average price dynamics in EA countries. We can observe a considerable variation in these values at the simultaneous extensive deviations between them, which show no definite upward or downward trend. It is also evident in the bottom figure as considerable changes in the range, which for the EA falls within the range of <2.2, 6.3>, while for standard deviation it is <0.63, 1.25>. In view of the low values of inflation rates in the euro area countries and the ECB inflation target itself, these differences turn out to be relatively large. It should also be stressed here that the variation for the entire EU in the analyzed period is much broader than for the euro area. In this case, the range is <2.7, 13.1>, while standard deviation is <0.62, 2.28>. Nevertheless, a posi- tive result is connected with the increasing convergence of both meas- ures for the EA and the EU in recent years, particularly since 2014.5 However, regional differences in the general price level dynamics in the EA are evident, and this fact should be taken into consideration both in the methodology for the criterion of nominal convergence and the value of the ECB inflation target. 5   Cf. research on the differences in price dynamics in the euro area with the use of an interesting, different econometric methodology. The authors come to the conclu- sion, which is confirmed in this article, that the analyzed differences should disappear in the future, and additionally do not undermine the legitimacy of the inflation target of the ECB (Weber, Beck, 2005).
  • 10. 108 Paweł Błaszczyk, Łukasz Fojutowski ŚSP 3 ’18 Fig. 1. Assessment of regional differences in the general price level dynamics in the euro area, as compared to that of the entire European Union 2004–2017 6.0 5.0 4.0 3.0 2.0 1.0 0.0 –1.0 –2.0 % 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015 2016 2017 max EA – spread min EA – stand. dev. average EU – spread Minimum, maximum and average general price level dynamics in the euro area in 20042017 15.0 10.0 5.0 0.0 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015 2016 2017 EU – stand. dev. Range and standard deviation of general price level dynamics in the euro area and the EU in 20042017 Source: Authors’ study based on Eurostat data.
  • 11. ŚSP 3 ’18 Convergence of price dynamics assessed in view of Poland’s... 109 2. Assessment of Poland’s nominal convergence with the euro area in terms of the general price level dynamics The aim of the empirical study was to assess Poland’s convergence with the euro area in terms of price dynamics, both in terms of short-term compliance to the Maastricht criterion and long-term prospects for con- formity to the ECB’s unified monetary policy. The analyzed period was set as the years 2004–2017. The starting point marks Poland’s accession to the EU and the resulting possibility to apply for accession to the euro area. The closing time point is connected with the availability of data for analysis. Convergence was assessed taking into consideration both the Maas- tricht criterion in its original form, and the authors’ proposal of a meth- odology formulated based on the observations presented in the previous chapter of this paper. In this context, several solutions modifying the methodology for this criterion need to be proposed. Eliminating from the EU reference group those countries, in which• deflation is recorded, and instead considering only countries with zero and/or positive price dynamics, or possibly the adoption of a minimum value of the criterion e.g. at 15%. In this way, a guarantee could be provided for a protection barrier against deflation amounting to 1.5 pp. A comparison of such a determined criterion to the methodology failing to exclude countries experiencing deflation is presented in Fig. 2. Establishment of the criterion at the level of the ECB inflation target• with an admissible fluctuation barrier, e.g. an arbitrary 0.5 pp. In this way, we would ensure the stability of the criterion and the constancy of its value for the candidate country, while the target would be sym- metrical in character, i.e. it would treat inflation and deflation threats equally, taking into consideration the antideflation barrier of 1.5 pp, and additionally it would refer to the value which will be binding in the long-term perspective of EA membership (Fig. 3). Establishment of the criterion at the level of average price dynamics• in the euro area with the admissible fluctuation barrier, identified, for example, based on the statistics concerning variation in price dynam- ics within the EA (standard deviation, range, etc., see Fig. 3). The strength of this variant stems from the fact that it refers to the situation in which the current average price dynamics in the euro area deviates from the target value of 2%. In this way, thus established, the crite- rion would more effectively refer to the current economic situation,
  • 12. 110 Paweł Błaszczyk, Łukasz Fojutowski ŚSP 3 ’18 and it would refer to the EA rather than the entire EU. Additionally, this variant would take into consideration the general price level dy- namics as an argument in the discussion on the inflation target value (see formula 1). This methodology may also be supplemented by the minimum upper level for the criterion (e.g. 1.5% or 2% – compare the ECB target) (Fig. 3). Price dynamics in Poland (HICP) in view of such formulated variants of the criteria in the years 2004–2017 are presented in Figs. 2 and 3. In Fig. 2, we can observe considerable differences in the criterion values when comparing the original methodology assuming the incorporation of reference countries experiencing deflation and the values obtained when the above-mentioned countries are excluded from the analysis. The differences are mainly evident in the years 2009–2010, i.e. during the global financial and economic crisis, and 2013–2016, i.e. in the face of downward trends in raw material prices, including oil prices on global markets. In those years, except for 2013, the value of the criterion when deflation was not excluded from analysis was dangerously low, drop- ping below 1%. During the 14 investigated years, Poland would have met the criterion 8 times, including the last 5 years, and interestingly, this would be the case irrespective of the potential exclusion of the coun- tries experiencing deflation. In recent years, despite the low value of the criterion, price dynamics in Poland were also very low, and consistent with the global trends in this respect in view of decreasing raw material prices. This convergence was found under the effect of demand factors, whereas during the crisis and the resulting negative demand shock (e.g. in 2009) it was no longer observed. Macroeconomically, in that period, our economy was in relatively good shape6 and for this reason it was not subject to deflationary processes. However, if at that time it had been necessary to meet the Maastricht criterion, restrictive monetary (or pos- sibly fiscal) policies would have been required in order to adapt to the ‘unnaturally’ low criterion value, generating tremendous socio-economic costs as a consequence. Additionally, taking into consideration reference countries experiencing deflation would cause an absurd situation (see Fig. 2) in which in some years the ECB itself would not meet the Maastricht criterion (see average price dynamics for the EA). Such a controversial situation clearly shows the flaws of the currently applied methodology for 6   It is evidenced by studies applying an original method based on a multifactorial economic assessment measure (Błaszczyk, 2015).
  • 13. ŚSP 3 ’18 Convergence of price dynamics assessed in view of Poland’s... 111 the Maastricht inflation criterion and thus it confirms the advisability of its adjustment. Thus, we can propose the exclusion of countries experiencing defla- tion (Fig. 2) from the current methodology, which would result in the minimum value of the criterion being 1.5%, i.e. at a level which in eco- nomic central banking practice refers to the lower values considered opti- mal in relation to price stability (compare the inflation target for Poland). For example, such a methodological approach applied for the middle of the 2009 crisis and under the global deflation trends in 2014–2016 would result in the criterion value being arbitrarily limited and never dropping below 1%, i.e. a value inconsistent with the contemporary definitions of price stability in Europe and worldwide. Additionally, average price dy- namics in the EA would take values below the criterion limit. Fig. 2. Price dynamics in Poland and the EA in the years 2004–2017 in view of the original methodology for the Maastricht criterion and following the exclusion of countries experiencing deflation 5 4 3 2 1 0 –1 % 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015 2016 2017 excluding deflation HICP Poland including deflation HICP EA Source: Authors’ study based on Eurostat data. While convergence in price dynamics is crucial in view of overall economic integration in Europe, and at the present stage of compliance with the unified monetary policy of the Monetary Union, a question arises whether it should be verified in relation to EU member states, or rather to countries with the lowest price dynamics. This is a major issue, since
  • 14. 112 Paweł Błaszczyk, Łukasz Fojutowski ŚSP 3 ’18 the candidate country, in order to reduce the costs related to the loss of autonomy in the monetary and exchange rate policies and the resulting potential threat to the unified monetary policy, should adapt in terms of price dynamics to the average trend in the euro area. It is the EA aver- age, rather than the lowest price dynamics in the EU, that is the primary benchmark for actions undertaken by the ECB and an element of the im- pulse response function. Nevertheless, the former should be taken into consideration within the multiparametric approach, including regional variation in price dynamics (compare below). For this reason, we need to consider the methodology of the crite- rion referring to the ECB inflation target with the admissible fluctua- tion barrier arbitrarily established at, say, 0.5%. In Figure 3, the upper and lower values of such a determined criterion are marked with black and red broken lines (the target plus 0.5, the target minus 0.5). In view of the above, Poland would have serious problems with meeting the accession criterion. The price dynamics is so unstable that it would have fallen within the target range only in 2017, while it would have exceeded it 7 times and been below it 5 times. While the proposed methodology is justified logically and factually, in practice it might prove too harsh for candidate countries (for comparison, see price dy- namics for the EA). Since price dynamics do not always need to comply with the ECB target, e.g. due to global demand or supply trends, including those result- ing from raw material prices, the next proposed change in the criterion methodology refers to the average price dynamics in the EA. The cri- terion would include admissible upward and downward fluctuations by the value of standard deviation, possibly including the minimum value of the criterion for the upper limit at 1.5 or 2% (which would refer to the ECB target and ‘safe’ inflation values). This approach to a certain degree would take into consideration regional variations in price dynamics and the H-B-S effect. Such a specified criterion is shown in Fig. 3 as the black (stand. dev. plus) and red (stand. dev. minus) dotted lines. In view of the above, Poland would have met the criterion requirements 8 times, it would have exceeded it 3 times, and Poland would have failed twice to reach the lower limit by a slight margin. This may be generally considered to be a good result, on the one hand showing the correct choice of criterion methodology, while on the other hand indicating the convergence of price dynamics in Poland with that in the euro area. The first conclusion is difficult to verify defini-
  • 15. ŚSP 3 ’18 Convergence of price dynamics assessed in view of Poland’s... 113 tively. However, further studies need to be conducted on the authors’ proposal for optimal inflation, focusing on the uniformity of the mon- etary policy and price differentiations in the Monetary Union, even if it seems factually sound and compliant with economic practice in terms of price stability. The second conclusion is doubtful, since price dynamics (see Figs. 2 and 3) in Poland for the entire period of analysis differed from that of the EA and were less stable (except for 2017, with 1.6% and 1.5%, respec- tively). In certain years, the price dynamic was greater, while in others it was lower. The average for the 2004–2017 period for Poland was higher and amounted to 2.1%, whereas for the EA it was 1.7%. The weak con- vergence of price dynamics in Poland to that of the EA is presented more comprehensively in Fig. 4 in relation to price levels (and not as previously – the rate of changes in price dynamics). Fig. 3. Price dynamics in Poland and the EA in the years 2004–2017 in view of proposed changes in the Maastricht criterion methodology 5.0 4.0 3.0 2.0 1.0 0.0 –1.0 % 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015 2016 2017 stand. dev. (minus) target (plus 0.5) HICP Poland stand. dev. (plus) target (minus 0.5) HICP EA Source: Authors’ study based on Eurostat data.
  • 16. 114 Paweł Błaszczyk, Łukasz Fojutowski ŚSP 3 ’18 Fig. 4. Price levels in Poland and in the EA in the years 2004–2017 with 2005 as the benchmark 130 120 110 100 90 EA Poland 2004M01 2004M09 2005M05 2006M01 2006M09 2007M05 2008M01 2008M09 2009M05 2010M01 2010M09 2011M05 2012M01 2012M09 2013M05 2014M01 2014M09 2015M05 2016M01 2016M09 2017M05 Source: Authors’ study based on Eurostat data. In this approach, considerable convergence was observed in the period until the global financial and economic crisis of the first decade of the 21st century. Next, we can observe an increase in price levels in Poland above the EA level, which is consistent with the fact that in a developing country increased GDP dynamics B is accompanied by price dynamics. The divergence in price levels stopped around 2013. Since then, we can observe a degree of stabilization or even slight progress in convergence for both time series. Conclusion The Polish economy is undergoing a continuous convergence process, as it is developing in the context of European integration, and – particu- larly – of the possible accession to the euro area. The necessary pre-con- dition for the adoption of euro is connected with meeting the Maastricht
  • 17. ŚSP 3 ’18 Convergence of price dynamics assessed in view of Poland’s... 115 criteria. In recent years, we have been witnessing progress in this field, particularly in fiscal aspects. In terms of the monetary sphere analyzed in this paper, particularly the general price level dynamics, in recent years the inflation criterion would also have been met, both in terms of its origi- nal methodology and the authors’ original proposal to adjust it. However, this does not mean that the monetary authorities may have no concerns over meeting the inflation criterion in the future, when the political decision on accession to the euro area is finally made. In con- trast, due to the relative character of this criterion its value is not certain. In particular, the European and global economic situation, by affecting domestic price dynamics including the reference countries, strongly de- termines its level. The last decade at the global demand and supply eco- nomic shocks and deflation showed that it may be very low, even close to zero. There is no consensus on the identification of reference countries experiencing deflation. As a consequence the criterion value may prove very low, inconsistent with the ECB inflation target, and more broadly with the definition of price stability applied in central banking practice both in Europe and worldwide. Such a situation may irrationally increase the costs associated with accession to the euro area also in the longer time frame. The methodology for establishing the Maastricht inflation criterion should be modified to take into consideration the threat of excessively low inflation, such as for example downward nominal wage rigidity, the lower nominal interest rate limit as well as regional variation in price dynamics in the Monetary Union. On the one hand, this methodology needs to treat the inflation and deflation threat symmetrically, while on the other hand it should also refer both to the average price dynamics in the euro area and the ECB inflation target. The proposals contained in this paper meet these requirements; nevertheless, further studies need to be conducted, e.g. also including the experiences of countries other than Poland. It should be taken into account that Poland’s accession to the euro area, which has the status of a country with a derogation, is basically a foregone conclusion. The question is not whether we want to enter the Economic and Monetary Union, but when? The decision is mainly con- ditioned by political will. The current economic situation, in particular with regard to the nominal Maastricht criteria, is beneficial and provides real grounds for their fulfillment in the coming years. Rational decision- makers, in determining the date of accession, should therefore take into account social and economic factors, including the criterion of price sta-
  • 18. 116 Paweł Błaszczyk, Łukasz Fojutowski ŚSP 3 ’18 bility considered here, and not only purely political premises, including electoral ones. Bibliography Akerlof G. A., Dickens W. T., Perry G. L. (1996), The Macroeconomics of Low Infla- tion, Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, vol. 1. Akerlof G. A., Dickens W. T., Perry G. L. (2000), Near-Rational Wage and Price Set- ting and the Optimal Rates of Inflation and Unemployment, Brooking Papers on Economic Activity, vol. 1. Aldasoro J. I., Zdarek V. (2009), Inflation Differentials in the Euro Area and their De- terminants – an empirical view, William Davidson Institute Working Paper, no. 958, April. Błaszczyk P. (2010), Stabilność cen – sposoby definicji oraz konsekwencje dla polityki pieniężnej, Materiały i Studia NBP, no. 249. Błaszczyk P. (2014), Wybrane problemy definicji stabilności cen w odniesieniu do strefy euro in: Gospodarka w warunkach integracji europejskiej, eds. D. J. Mierzejewski, J. Polcyn, Państwowa Wyższa Szkoła Zawodowa w Pile, Piła, pp. 13–24. Błaszczyk P. (2015), Post-crisis macroeconomic comparative assessment of the Eu- rozone member states with the use of an improved misery index, “Journal of Business & Economic Policy,” no. 3. Błaszczyk P. (2016), Price Level Dynamics Differentiation as a Problem of Defini- tion of Price Stability in the Euro Area, “Business Research Review,” vol. 2, no. 1. Chmielewski T. (2003), Od kursu płynnego do unii monetarnej. Znaczenie efektu Balassy-Samuelsona dla polskiej polityki pieniężnej, “Materiały i Studia NBP,” no. 163. Cukrowski J. (2001), Renta emisyjna jako źródło finansowania budżetu państwa, CASE, Warszawa. De Grauwe P. (2003), Unia walutowa. Funkcjonowanie i wyzwania, PWE, Warszawa. Devicienti F. (2004), Downward Nominal Wage Rigidity in Italy: Evidence and Con- sequences, LABORatorio R. Revelli Working Paper, no. 20. ECB (2003), Background Studies for the ECB’s Evaluation of its Monetary Policy Strategy, https://www.ecb.europa.eu/pub/pdf/other/monetarypolicystrat- egyreview_backgrounden, 29.07.2018. Ekberg J. (2002), Nominal Wage Rigidity on the Swedish Labor Market, Mimeo, Stockholm School of Economics. Fehr E., Goette L. (2000), Robustness and Real Consequences of Nominal Wage Ri- gidity, “Journal of Monetary Economics,” vol. 52 no. 2005.
  • 19. ŚSP 3 ’18 Convergence of price dynamics assessed in view of Poland’s... 117 Friedman B. L. (red.), Solow R. M., Taylor J. B. (2002), Inflacja, bezrobocie a poli- tyka monetarna, CeDeWu, Warszawa. IMF, International Monetary Fund (1999), Safeguarding Macroeconomic Stability at Low Inflation, World Economic Outlook, October. Keynes J. M. (2003), Ogólna teoria zatrudnienia, procentu i pieniądza, PWN, Warszawa. Kilian L., Manganelli S. (2007), Quantifying the Risk of Deflation, “Journal of Money, Credit and Banking,” vol. 39, nos. 2–3. Kimura T., Ueda K. (1997), Downward Nominal Wage Rigidity in Japan: Is Price Stability Costly?, Bank of Japan Working Paper. Knoppik C., Beissinger T. (2001), How Rigid are Nominal Wages? Evidence and Impli- cations for Germany, “Scandinavian Journal of Monetary Economics,” no. 105. Kumar M. S., Baig T., Decressin J., Faulkner-MacDonagh C., Feyzioglu T. (2003), Deflation. Determinants, Risks, and Policy Options, International Monetary Fund, Occasional Paper, no. 221. Kwiatkowski E. (2002), Bezrobocie. Podstawy teoretyczne, PWN, Warszawa. Lebow D. E., Saks R. E., Wilson B. A. (2003), Downward Nominal Wage Rigidity. Evidence from the Employment Cost Index, “Advances in Macroeconomics,” vol. 3. Molle W. (2000), Ekonomika integracji europejskiej. Teoria, praktyka, polityka, Fun- dacja Gospodarcza, Gdańsk. Moretti L. (2014), Determinants of inflation differentials in the euro area, CFS Work- ing Paper Series, no. 451, Center for Financial Studies. NBP (2009), Raport na temat pełnego uczestnictwa Rzeczypospolitej Polskiej w trze- cim etapie Unii Gospodarczej i Walutowej, Warszawa. Nickell S. J., Quintini G. (2003), Nominal Wage Rigidity and the Rate of Inflation, “Mimeo. The Economic Journal,” no. 113. Ochryniuk M., Rogut A. (2010), Konwergencja nominalna w strefie euro. Implikacje dla Polski, NBP, https://www.nbp.pl/publikacje/o_euro/konwergencja_nomi- nalna.pdf. 30.07.2018. Pronobis M. (2008), Polska w strefie euro, C.H. Beck, Warszawa. Social Security Administration (1996), The Boskin Commission Report, Toward a More Accurate Measure of the Cost of Living, https://www.ssa.gov/history/ reports/boskinrpt.html (30.01.2018) Svensson L. E. O. (2000), How should monetary policy be conducted in an area of price stability?, NBER Working Paper, no. 7516. Szeląg K. (1998), Wprowadzenie euro – geneza, kluczowe decyzje, aspekty prawne, „Bank i Kredyt,” no. 10. Walkowski M. (2012), Unia Europejska – rozpad czy powrót do równowagi makro- ekonomicznej i finansowej? Rozważania na temat kryzysu w strefie euro z per- spektywy europejskiej i światowej, „Środkowoeuropejskie Studia Polityczne,” no. 3.
  • 20. 118 Paweł Błaszczyk, Łukasz Fojutowski ŚSP 3 ’18 Weber A. A., Beck G. W. (2005), Price Stability, Inflation Convergence and Diversity in EMU: Does One Size Fit All?, Center for Financial Studies, no. 2005/30. Wojtyna A. (2001), Skuteczność polityki pieniężnej w warunkach niskiej inflacji: problem zerowej granicy nominalnych stóp procentowych, „Bank i Kredyt,” no. 7. Wojtyna A. (2004), Szkice o polityce pieniężnej, PWE, Warszawa. Wójcik C. (2008), Integracja ze strefą euro. Teoretyczne i praktyczne aspekty konwer- gencji, PWN, Warszawa. Wynne M., Rodriguez-Palenzuela D. (2002), Measurement Bias in the HICP: What Do We Know and What Do We Need to Know?, Federal Reserve Bank of Dal- las Working Paper, no. 206. Zombirt J. (2008), Mechanizmy rynku wewnętrznego Unii Europejskiej, Difin, Warszawa. Zwierzchlewski S. (2015), Stabilność unii walutowej, Wydawnictwo A. Marszałek, Toruń. Ocena konwergencji dynamiki cen w perspektywie akcesji Polski do strefy euro ze szczególnym uwzględnieniem deflacji Streszczenie Podstawowym celem opracowania jest ocena stopnia konwergencji Polski w za- kresie stabilności cen, zarówno na etapie kandydowania do strefy euro i w odniesieniu do kryteriów z Maastricht, jak i w szerszym ujęciu w kontekście jednolitej polityki pieniężnej EBC. Zakres czasowy badania obejmuje okres 2004–2017. Dolna cezura czasowa wynika z przystąpienia Polski do UE, co warunkuje możliwość ubiegania się o przynależność do strefy euro. Górna cezura czasowa wynika z dostępności danych, głównie w odniesieniu do Eurostat. Realizacja celu została dokonana na tle analizy krytycznej metodyki i sposobu wyznaczania kryterium z Maastricht dotyczącego dy- namiki ogólnego poziomu cen. Metodyka wyznaczania kryterium inflacyjnego jest wadliwa i niedopasowana do współczesnych uwarunkowań gospodarczych, w tym na tle definicji stabilności cen stosowanych w praktyce bankowości centralnej, a tak- że w kontekście zjawiska deflacji powszechnie występującego w ostatniej dekadzie. W konsekwencji wartość kryterium dla kraju kandydującego może okazać się bar- dzo niska i może w nieuzasadniony sposób zwiększać koszty akcesji do strefy euro, również w długim horyzoncie czasowym. Taki problem powinien być uwzględniany w dyskusji na temat akcesji Polski do strefy euro, która przeważnie ma charakter poli- tyczny i dalej społeczny oraz ekonomiczny. To aspekt ekonomiczny jednak powinien być w praktyce kluczowy. Słowa kluczowe: deflacja, integracja gospodarcza, strefa euro, polityka pieniężna, stabilność cen