SlideShare a Scribd company logo
1 of 18
Download to read offline
DOI 10.14746/ssp.2019.2.4
Maciej Olejnik
Centrum Studiów Niemieckich i Europejskich im. Willy’ego Brandta
Uniwersytetu Wrocławskiego
ORCID: 0000-0002-8697-3158
The influence of illiberal democracy
on the effectiveness of attempts to control lobbying
in Hungary (2010–2014)
Abstract: Lobbying, understood as all actions performed by or on behalf of interest
groups directed at influencing of the process of policy formation and implementation,
occurs in every political regime. The article examines whether the illiberal type of
democracy that exists in Hungary (2010–2014) exerts an influence on the effective-
ness of lobbying control.
  Illiberal democracy differs from liberal democracy with regard to five systemic core
principles, such as the rule of law, government control and accountability, the integrity
of political elites, media freedom and civil rights and protection of minorities. This
article shows that all of these systemic criteria constituting illiberal democracy were
met in Hungary between 2010–2014. Examination of the case of Hungary with regard
to lobbying control suggests that illiberal democracy had diminished the effectiveness
of lobbying control in this country.
Key words: illiberal democracy, lobbying, Hungary, liberal democracy, rule of law
Introduction
Lobbying occurs in various forms in almost every known political
system. Due to the fact that it is almost impossible to eliminate it
from the political system, governments, especially in democracies, are
interested in devising ways to control lobbying effectively. Lobbying may
become a useful tool, which enables members of the parliament and the
government to gain knowledge about interest groups’ main problems and
find solutions to them. However, there is a risk that citizens will not have
the possibility to obtain information about the way in which political de-
cisions are made (i.e., how and who is trying to influence the government
during the process of policy-making) unless lobbying is regulated effi-
ciently. This issue is especially significant in contemporary democratic
66	 Maciej Olejnik	 ŚSP 2 ’19
states, in which the legislative and executive branch of power is elected
(directly or indirectly) by the citizens, none of whom should be privileged
above others. Democracy can be protected only if the state and interest
groups establish clear rules guaranteeing that lobbying organizations are
“transparent and accountable and bound by common standards of good
practice and ethical conduct” (Parvin, 2007, p. 34). For instance, Philip
Parvin indicates that if lobbying is carried out in this way, it can even
strengthen “parliamentary democracy, providing new and diverse chan-
nels through which different groups and the wider public might feed into
the democratic system” (Parvin, 2007, p. 34).
There are some significant differences among political and social
scientists regarding the definition of lobbying. Gary Armstrong and Phi-
lip Kotler argue that lobbying means “building and maintaining relations
with legislators and government officials [in order] to influence legisla-
tion and regulation” (Armstrong, Kotler, 2010, p. 472). Their definition
emphasizes the role of personal relationships that exist between members
of parliament or the executive branch and lobbyists. It excludes any gras-
sroots action (e.g. email campaigns, demonstrations) from the sphere of
lobbying. In contrast, Wyn Grant perceives lobbying as a wider phenome-
non: “Lobbying refers to attempts to exert influence on the formation or
implementation of public policy” (Grant, 2003a, p. 314). This interpreta-
tion assumes that lobbying activities include all kinds of relations betwe-
en lobbyists and authorities, as well as other actions in which members of
the latter group are not directly involved, such as demonstrations, strikes,
and television and internet campaigns. Wyn Grant’s definition seems to be
better suited to modern democratic states than Gary Armstrong and Philip
Kotler’s concept. Of course, many political decisions are still reached
during meetings between lobbyists and the authorities. However, bottom-
up actions through which lobbyists try to influence authorities also often
end successfully. For instance, Daniel Bergan’s experiment conducted on
the members of the New Hampshire state legislature confirmed this. The
result of this research shows that email lobbying campaigns substantially
influenced legislators’ voting behavior (Bergen, 2009, pp. 327–352).
Political and social scientists have some difficulties in identifying who
actually performs lobbying activity. Clive Thomas and Ronald Hrebenar
created one of the broadest classifications, distinguishing five groups of
lobbyists: contract lobbyists; in-house lobbyists; government legislative
liaisons; citizen, cause or volunteer lobbyists; and private individuals,
‘hobbyists’ or self-appointed lobbyists (Thomas, 2004, pp. 152–153).
ŚSP 2 ’19	 The influence of illiberal democracy on the effectiveness...	 67
Lobbyists from the first four groups always act on behalf of someone else
(e.g. corporations, companies and local governments which employ them,
or non-profit organizations). Members of the last group “lobby for pet
projects, direct personal benefits or against a policy or proposal they find
particularly objectionable” (Thomas, 2004, p. 153). Lester Milbrath pre-
sented a different approach to this issue. In this perspective, every attempt
at impacting the government’s political decisions should be treated as an
example of lobbying if it is carried out “by someone other than a citizen
acting on his own behalf” (Milbrath, 1968, p. 442). From this point of
view, a person who tries to achieve their political interests individually
by influencing the government should not be treated as a lobbyist. This
might be a very reasonable position, as it seems virtually impossible to
effectively analyze lobbying if we consider people who undertake any po-
litical action in their own political interest (such as criticizing government
decisions that directly affect them on Facebook) to be lobbyists. For the
purpose of this article, I consider lobbyists to be only those entities which
try to affect authorities’ political decisions on behalf of interest groups.
Wyn Grant defines interest groups as “organizations seeking to advance
a particular sectional interest or cause while not seeking to form a go-
vernment or part of a government” (Grant, 2003b, p. 266). This definition
embraces non-profit associations, trade unions, companies and any other
institution that is even partially involved in the process of policy-making
unless it also tries to formally gain power in the country. In the latter part
of the article, the term ‘lobbying’ refers to all actions performed by or on
behalf of interest groups directed at the influencing the process of policy
formation and implementation.
One of the most crucial aspects of studies on lobbying relates to its ef-
fective control. Lobbying is effectively controlled if it is completely trans-
parent, which means that the public have easy access to the following in-
formation: “(a) who is lobbying public representatives, (b) on what issues
they are being lobbied, (c) when and how they are being lobbied, (d) how
much is being spent in the process, (e) what is the result of these lobbying
efforts?” (Bartha, 2014, p. 7), and the authorities cannot refuse to share
this information with the public. Four out of five systemic core principles
that constitute liberal democracy enhance the effectiveness of lobbying
control in the state. These features include: the government following the
rule of law, especially with regard to the stability, explicitness and gene-
ral and prospective nature of passed laws; the existence of completely
independent institutions which can verify whether the government is fol-
68	 Maciej Olejnik	 ŚSP 2 ’19
lowing the rule of law, as well as repeal any unconstitutional laws; low
levels of corruption among political elites, which discourages interests
groups from illegally influencing politicians’ decisions (i.e. bribery); and
fully free, autonomous media outlets which are critical of the government
and are capable of investigating ties between the government and interest
groups. These systemic core principles allow the legislative process to be
conducted in an entirely transparent way. The fifth principle – civil rights
and protection of minorities – is not a meaningful factor affecting the
effectiveness of lobbying control.
Against this backdrop, the aim of this article is to examine whether
the illiberal model of democracy in Hungary influenced the effectiveness
of attempts to control lobbying between 2010–2014, or whether it was
irrelevant in this regard. Within this period of time, Hungary transfor-
med from a liberal to an illiberal democracy. I argue that the worsening
quality of democracy in illiberal democracies, mainly with regard to the
rule of law, the takeover of previously independent oversight institutions
by the ruling political parties, the considerable rise in corruption practi-
ces among members of the government, and the partial decline of media
freedom may also have consequences on the effectiveness of lobbying
control. Thus, I suggest the following hypothesis: the illiberal model of
democracy exerts a negative influence on the effectiveness of lobbying
control in Hungary.
The Hungarian example was examined because there is a predominant
opinion in academic discourse that, since 2010, Hungary has rejected the
path of socio-political development towards liberal democracy, choosing
its illiberal version instead (Karolewski, Benedikter, 2017, pp. 179–180,
184–185). Analysis of the Hungarian case study will be treated as an in-
troduction to a discussion of the possible correlation between the illiberal
model of democracy and the effectiveness of lobbying control worldwide.
This analysis is innovative as no research showing this type of correlation
seems to exist.
Systemic criteria constituting liberal and illiberal democracy
Democracy has radically changed over the centuries in terms of its
size, scale and scope (Schmitter, 2011, pp. 191–192), as well as with re-
gard to many further aspects (Schmitter, 2011, pp. 193–198). Currently,
a country is identified as democratic only if some guarantees are anchored
ŚSP 2 ’19	 The influence of illiberal democracy on the effectiveness...	 69
institutionally, in particular free, regular and competitive elections, fre-
edom of association, freedom of speech and access to various, alternative
sources of information (Dahl’s concept of full polyarchy) (Dahl, 2005,
p. 332). We can distinguish two types of democracy (liberal and illiberal
democracy) that fulfill all elements of full polyarchy. They operate dif-
ferently with regard to the five systemic core principles (the rule of law,
government control and accountability, integrity of political elites, media
freedom and civil rights and protection of minorities).
The first distinction between liberal and illiberal democracy concerns
the rule of law. In this article, the term is defined as “compliance with
the law, when the law is general, public, prospective, clear, consistent,
performable, and stable” (Sánchez-Cuenca, 2003, p. 69). In the illiberal
democratic country, laws are not constructed and implemented according
to those principles. Moreover, in illiberal democracies, the government
often does not follow the rule of law unless it suits the interests of the
power elite. Conversely, in liberal democracies the rule of law is applied
in most of the cases. Rare violations of the rule of law also occur in libe-
ral democracies, but such situations take place considerably less often in
liberal than illiberal democracies. The second difference concerns con-
trol over government actions and accountability. In liberal democracies,
there are independent institutions (e.g. the Constitutional Tribunal, the
Supreme Court or the lower courts), which can convict politicians even
if they belong to the ruling elite and repeal government policies if they
are illegal. Furthermore, these decisions are respected and implemented
by the government or other public institutions. In illiberal democratic co-
untries, the government either does not recognize unfavorable decisions
or subjugates these institutions according to their preferences (Merkel,
2004, p. 49).
The third distinction refers to the level of corruption. It is high in illibe-
ral democracies (Alonso, Keane, Merkel, 2011, p. 11), while political elites
are corrupt to the lesser extent in liberal democratic states. However, there
are no countries in which this kind of misuse of power has been completely
eliminated, even among the highly transparent and accountable elites of the
Scandinavian countries. This is why the criteria of media freedom – the fo-
urth dissimilarity between the analyzed political regimes – are so crucial for
the survival of a liberal democracy. Liberal democracies are characterized
by fully free media. It is often media outlets that reveal corrupt practices
among the authorities in liberal democratic states. Media activity can lead
to a politician’s fall from grace and even to convictions in liberal democra-
70	 Maciej Olejnik	 ŚSP 2 ’19
cies. The media are only partially free in the illiberal democracy (Alonso,
Keane, Merkel, 2011, p. 11). A significant number of them are controlled
by the ruling political parties or their allies. Nevertheless, there are a few
influential media outlets which are independent and try to monitor the go-
vernment’s activity. This is one of the crucial differences between illiberal
democracies and authoritarian systems.
The fifth difference between liberal and illiberal democracy involves
civil rights and the state’s policies regarding minorities. In illiberal demo-
cratic countries, civil rights are often partially suspended (Merkel, 2004,
p. 49), and minorities are also exposed to discrimination. On the other
hand, civil rights function flawlessly in the liberal democracies, in parti-
cular due to the independent system of courts. Liberal democracies pro-
tect minorities and guarantee their “right to speak their languages, prac-
tice their culture and express their identities” (Diamond, 2002, p. 213).
Table 1 summarizes the comparative analysis of liberal and illiberal de-
mocracy through the prism of areas differentiating these political regimes
(cf. Alonso, Keane, Merkel, 2011, p. 11).
Table 1
Discrepancies between the systemic criteria constituting liberal
and illiberal democracies
Areas of differen-
tiation between
liberal and illib-
eral democracy
Systemic criteria
constituting liberal
democracy
Systemic criteria constituting
illiberal democracy
1 2 3
The rule of law The government usually fol-
lows the rule of law.
The government often breaches the
rule of law if it is in its political inter-
est to do so.
Government con-
trol and account-
ability
There are institutions in-
dependent from the gov-
ernment, which can hold
political elites accountable
and have the right to repeal
their unlawful policies. The
government recognizes all
decisions made by the inde-
pendent institutions.
The government is not de facto over-
seen by any institution. The govern-
ment rejects implementing decisions
taken by oversight bodies which are
unfavorable to it. These institutions
are deprived of the majority of their
competences or are captured by the
ruling political elites soon after they
form the government.
Integrity of politi-
cal elites
Political elites are corrupt to
a small extent
Corrupt political elites
Media freedom Free and independent media Majority of media controlled by the
government or its allies
ŚSP 2 ’19	 The influence of illiberal democracy on the effectiveness...	 71
1 2 3
Civil rights and
protection of mi-
norities
Citizens can benefit from
civil right law. Minorities’
rights are protected by the
law.
Some rights are suspended or abol-
ished. Minorities are exposed to dis-
crimination and are not protected by
the law.
Source: Own compilation based on S. Alonso, J. Keane, W. Merkel, Editors’ introduc-
tion: Rethinking the future of representative democracy, in: The Future of Representative
Democracy, eds. S. Alonso, J. Keane, W. Merkel, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge
2011, pp. 1–22; W. Merkel, Embedded and Defective Democracies, “Democratization,”
vol. 11, no. 5, December 2004, pp. 33–58.
Illiberal democracy’s influence on lobbying control in Hungary
Based on the comparative analysis of liberal and illiberal democracy
presented in this article, Hungary was part of the latter group of political
systems between 2010–2014. Five systemic criteria constituting illiberal
democracy were fulfilled in Hungary in this period of time.
The second government of Viktor Orbán (2010–2014) formed by the
Hungarian Civic Alliance (Fidesz) and the Christian Democratic People’s
Party (KDNP), which achieved a 2/3 majority in the parliamentary elec-
tions in 2010 (Magyar, 2016, p. 15), allowing parties to change the con-
stitution without the opposition’s consent, did not follow the rule of law
(Magyar, 2016, p. 289). In 2010, the Hungarian parliament repealed the
only law (The Lobbying Act) that comprehensively regulated lobbying in
Hungary (Bartha, 2014, p. 8), and since then has passed many laws which
were inconsistent with the rule of law. Some of these had a retroactive
effect, e.g. the law which obliged judges to retire at the age of 62 (it repla-
ced the act that allowed judges to serve until the age of 70) came into for-
ce without any transition period and also applied to judges who exceeded
this age before the act was adopted. In this way, hundreds of judges were
suddenly forced into retirement (Kovács, 2015, p. 283).
Between 2010–2014, the Hungarian parliament passed not only gene-
ral, but also many specific laws which aimed to enable corporations and
companies tied to the government to strengthen their position in the sector
of the economy within which they operated. New laws contained regula-
tions which supported selected companies against their competitors. Two
laws introducing an extra tax on financial institutions and imposing a new
tax on supermarkets are good illustrations of such practices. In the former
case, the new legislation imposed a tax on all insurance companies except
72	 Maciej Olejnik	 ŚSP 2 ’19
for those founded between 2007–2010. However, it turned out that there
was only one considerable insurance company (CIG) set up in this period
of time that could have taken advantage of the new law. It belonged to
Járai Zsigmond – a close associate of Prime Minister Viktor Orbán. Járai
Zsigmond was a Minister of Finance in his first government which was in
power between 1998–2002 (Bartha, 2014, pp. 29–30). The latter legisla-
tion set a tax that applied to all supermarket chains operating in Hungary
apart from the one (CBA) whose owners had close relations with mem-
bers of the government (Bartha, 2014, p. 29).
Any attempts to successfully control lobbying activity during the pro-
cess of law-making were ineffective due to the fact that, since 2010, Hun-
garian law has lacked other crucial features constituting the rule of law:
stability and explicitness. Even the most significant legal act in Hungary
– a new constitution that came into force in 2012 – was substantially
changed five times within three years (Kovács, 2015, p. 273). Further-
more, “the degree of legal uncertainty is also indicated by the unprece-
dentedly large number of acts (859) and amendments (538) passed during
the second Orbán government” (Ágh, Dieringer, Bönker, 2015, p. 16)
(the Hungarian parliament passed significantly fewer laws in its previous
terms; 587 between 2006–2010, 573 between 2002–2006 and 460 betwe-
en 1998–2002 [Archives of the Hungarian National Assembly, 2014]).
Many of these were presented to the public, proceeded and adopted by the
parliament within only one day, preventing any substantial debate on the
issue. For instance, the most crucial amendments to the ‘supermarket tax’
act have been passed that way (Bartha, 2014, p. 29). Moreover, due to the
fact that the law regulating access to public information turned out to be
very imprecise, it is extremely difficult and sometimes impossible to gain
any information regarding lobbyists’role in the process of policy-making,
even after the new law has been implemented. In 2010–2014, this law has
been changed many times (Kovács, 2015, p. 284, Hegedüs, 2016, p. 9)
so public institutions could take advantage of various vague provisions
and loopholes and refuse to release information concerning the process of
policy-making to the public.
Undoubtedly, the fact that Hungarian law was not stable and was not
created in an explicit way affected the effectiveness of lobbying control
substantially, especially with regard to such issues as who actually per-
formed lobbying activity, as well as what methods were applied and how
much money was spent. This is corroborated by the fact that even in-
stitutions (e.g. watchdogs) interested in examining whether any lobbyist
ŚSP 2 ’19	 The influence of illiberal democracy on the effectiveness...	 73
influenced the legislative process were unable to do so, because the speed
of the political decision-making was too fast to allow any meaningful
oversight. The process of creating specific laws should have been sub-
ject to close scrutiny, because their aim was to grant some companies an
operating advantage in a particular branch of the economy. It is therefore
no wonder that many interest groups attempted to influence the content
of these projects. Unfortunately, specific laws were not only proceeded in
the shortest possible time, but they were also frequently altered, so it was
impossible to find out how lobbying was carried out for these acts (for in-
stance, when and how members of the government were lobbied). Taking
those facts into consideration leads to the conclusion that considerable
deficiencies in the rule of law in Hungary diminished the effectiveness of
lobbying control in this country.
Since 2010, there have been no institutions in Hungary which could
effectively control the government’s activity, including relations betwe-
en its members and lobbyists. The Constitutional Tribunal attempted to
be such an institution in terms of law-making, especially during the first
three years of Viktor Orbán’s second government. For instance, in 2010
the Tribunal repealed the law that retroactively imposed a 98% tax on
severance pay in the public sector between 2005–2010 (Freedom House,
2011). However, the government, instead of honoring this ruling – as all
former governments had – reintroduced the same tax after the parliament
substantially slashed the Constitutional Tribunal’s competences. Within
four years, the Tribunal lost the majority of its competences, which left
it impotent in terms of effective judicial review. For instance, unless new
laws threaten citizens’ fundamental rights, the Constitutional Tribunal is
no longer allowed to examine cases related to the public budget (Ko-
vács, 2013, p. 261). This means that the Tribunal cannot verify whether
laws imposing new taxes on various branches of the economy are consi-
stent with the constitution, even if they directly favor specific companies
and thus constitute discrimination. Since April 2013, the majority of the
Constitutional Tribunal’s members have been nominated by Fidesz and
KDNP. From then on, all government decisions questioned by the oppo-
sition and non-governmental organizations have been ruled in favor of the
government (Hegedüs, 2016, pp. 8–9). Also, the judicial system has been
captured by the power elite. In particular, judges who had strong ties with
the ruling political parties were appointed to both lower courts and the
Supreme Court between 2010–2014. The lower courts made some deci-
sions which went against the government’s political interests, but in case
74	 Maciej Olejnik	 ŚSP 2 ’19
of the Supreme Court nearly all rulings were beneficial to the government
(Ágh, Dieringer, Bönker, 2015, pp. 16–17). Public officials, aware of the
fact that they would not be punished for breaking the law, sometimes deli-
berately delayed the implementation of courts’ decisions propitious to the
government’s opponents (Hegedüs, 2016, p. 10). Overall, it has produced
a political system in which the ruling parties can not only pass every
law without any negative legal consequences, but also forged an alliance
between the government and the companies owned either by the political
elite’s family members and cronies or employing them. As a result, these
companies support Fidesz and KDNP (i.e. via financing media favorable
to the government and refusing to buy advertisements in opposition media
outlets). During the frequent meetings between members of this alliance,
representatives of the companies influenced the government’s political
decisions on many crucial socio-economic matters, which were then im-
plemented within next couple of days (Bartha, 2014, p. 20). Neither po-
liticians nor representatives of the companies shared with the public any
information concerning the course of these meetings, the lobbyists’ aims
or information submitted to decision-makers.
In the majority of cases, the public could not obtain any information
about the process of policy-making that took place between the mem-
bers of the government and lobbyists during their meetings, because there
were no truly independent institutions which might force politicians to
reveal them, or convict these people if they refused to do so. Thus, it
can be stated that the effectiveness of lobbying control in Hungary was
negatively influenced by the fact that, in practice, not only can members
of the government not be held accountable or their decisions monitored,
but illiberal democracy in Hungary fostered collusion between the state
and some enterprises.
Against this backdrop, corruption has become a significant problem in
Hungary in terms of policy formation and implementation. While interest
groups initiate corrupt practices in the majority of democratic countries,
in Hungary it was the government that was mainly responsible for the
promotion of corruption. The government decided who would belong to
this politico-economic alliance, which had a corrupt nature. Within this
system, the coalition of ruling political parties used “its legislative power
to interfere with even minor segments of the economy and benefit its
private-sector clients” (Kovács, 2015, p. 286). A new law regulating the
trade in tobacco products is one striking example of this phenomenon.
In April 2013, the Fidesz-KDNP coalition passed the Tobacco Retailing
ŚSP 2 ’19	 The influence of illiberal democracy on the effectiveness...	 75
Act, which reduced the number of tobacco retail licenses from 40,000 to
5000 and redistributed them almost exclusively among companies that
had close ties with the members of the government. A couple of mon-
ths later, it introduced amendments to this law enabling companies that
possessed the license to remarkably increase their revenues. Journalists
accidentally discovered that one of the versions of the Tobacco Retailing
Act was prepared on the laptop of the CEO of a Hungarian tobacco com-
pany, János Sánta, which then obtained more than 10% of licenses. The
government admitted that János Sánta was involved in the legislation pro-
cess but it did not explain what the nature of his engagement was (e.g.
which members of the government did this person meet? What data and
expertise did he provide?) (Bartha, 2014, pp. 30–31). Consequently, the
public knew nothing about the way in which lobbying was carried out in
the case of the Tobacco Retailing Act. Citizens could only be certain that
the government’s allies took advantage of the new law. There were many
more cases of corruption concerning public procurement contracts, as
well as further corruption scandals between 2010–2014 (Hegedüs, 2016,
p. 10). There was a lack of transparency in the relations between lobbyists
and the government, and no attempts to enhance transparency were made
from either side. Thus, it should not be a surprise that Hungary obtained
a worse score (it was very low even before 2010) in studies on corruption
in 2014 than in the previous years, conducted by international organiza-
tions such as the World Justice Project (The World Justice Project, 2013,
p. 97; The World Justice Project, 2014, p. 100) and Freedom House (He-
gedüs, 2016, p. 1).
Corrupt politicians frequently tried to conceal compromising details
on their unofficial ties with interest groups from the public. Even when
watchdogs obtained a little information on secret lobbying practices (as
happened in case of the Tobacco Retailing Act), members of the Hun-
garian government did not provide any further details about them. They
were afraid that this information might discredit them and cause a loss in
their parties’ popularity. Thus, the public were deprived of any specifics
on uncontrolled lobbying, particularly with regard to the way in which
lobbying activities were carried out and the amount of money that was
involved in these practices. Undoubtedly, the fact that political elites were
corrupt to a very large extent notably reduced the effectiveness of lobby-
ing control in Hungary.
Freedom House has examined the media’s status in Hungary since
2002. Until 2010, it was rated as ‘free’ (Karlekar, 2010, p. 15; Karlekar
76	 Maciej Olejnik	 ŚSP 2 ’19
2011, p. 14). The score declined after the formation of the second Orbán
government. Since 2011, every year the media’s status in Hungary has
been described as ‘partially free’ by Freedom House (Karlekar, Dunham,
2012, p. 15; Karlekar, Dunham, 2013, p. 14; Karlekar, Dunham, 2014,
p. 20; Dunham, Nelson, Aghekyan, 2015, p. 22). This assessment is com-
pletely justified for several reasons. Firstly, the public media were taken
over by the government in 2010, and since then they have served as state
propaganda outlets (Kovács, 2013, p. 257). Even in the private sector, the
majority of newspapers, magazines, online news outlets and one of two
most powerful private television channels belong to companies that are
allied with the government (e.g., TV2, Metropol, Helyi Téma, Magyar
Nemzet [Bartha, 2014, p. 24; Kovács, 2015, p. 280]). They provide the
public solely with news and commentary that is favorable to the govern-
ment. Still, other powerful television channels, as well as some online
news outlets, remained neutral in Hungary throughout the second Orbán
government (e.g., RTL Klub, Origo.hu [Bartha, 2014, pp. 24–25; Kovács,
2015, p. 279]) but there were few opposition media outlets in this country
between 2010–2014 (e.g., Klubrádió, Népszabadság [Bartha, 2014, p. 24;
Kovács, 2014, 270]). Also, journalists restrained themselves in reporting
news that might be interpreted as hurting the government politically or le-
gally. This was caused by the fear of losing advertising revenue, which in
Hungary mainly comes from the state or companies allied with the ruling
parties. Between 2010–2014, opposition media outlets lost this source of
income to pro-government media. Journalists were also afraid that the
Media Council1
would impose considerable fines on the companies they
worked for if they revealed information that could be unfavorable to the
government.
Unsurprisingly, the vast majority of the media outlets did not under-
take any serious attempts to examine how lobbying was carried out in
Hungary in this political environment. Pro-government media outlets did
not want to do this because they supported Fidesz and KDNP. Any cor-
1
  The Media Council is an administrative organ of the National Media and In-
focommunications Authority, which is a regulatory body that “oversees all media,
public and private, including broadcast, print, and online outlets” (Kovács, “Hungary
in 2015”, p. 281). The Media Council has the right to impose significant fines for
activities that are very difficult to define, such as inciting hatred against majorities. Al-
though the Media Council is formally an autonomous institution, in fact it is strongly
biased in favor of the ruling parties as only government loyalists have been nominated
to this institution by the parliament.
ŚSP 2 ’19	 The influence of illiberal democracy on the effectiveness...	 77
ruption scandals, including those involving lobbying activity, could cause
the government to lose popularity and thus power. In turn, this would al-
most certainly mean also the loss of revenue for these media outlets, since
state-owned companies controlled by the current opposition would not
buy advertisements in these outlets. While the ‘neutral’ media abstained
from closely investigating specific relations between the government and
its allied companies, because they also wanted to sell advertisements to
them, the opposition media did not have enough resources to be able to
carefully examine lobbying activities.
The role of the media is to investigate various lobbying practices and
disclose information about them to the society if public institutions let
citizens down in this matter. However, in the majority of cases, the Hun-
garian media either did not want to or were not able to discover who the
lobbyists that tried to influence the government’s policy were, how they
did this and what were the results of their actions. Without any doubt, the
lack of complete media freedom diminished the effectiveness of lobbying
control in Hungary.
Hungary did not fully protect civil rights or minorities from discrimina-
tion even before Orbán formed his second government in 2010 (Freedom
House, 2010), but these problems deepened significantly afterwards. Al-
though the Romani people constitute by far the largest ethnic minority in
Hungary (about 5–7% of Hungarians), they have few representatives in
the parliament and have long been treated as ‘second-class citizens,’ e.g.
many Romani children were put into schools for children with mental di-
sabilities (Freedom House, 2014).This population also suffered from ha-
rassment and hate speech, which usually did not meet with the proper re-
sponse from the public institutions (Ágh, Dieringer, Bönker, 2016, p. 16).
The LGBT community was another minority facing similar problems, as
the police and members of the government were among the groups that
were responsible for harassing LGBT people (Freedom House, 2016).
Various religious groups have also been treated unequally in Hungary.
In 2011, the Hungarian parliament passed the law on the legal status of
churches, which divided religious organizations into two types: religious
communities (90% of religious organizations belong to this group) and
churches. Only organizations from the latter group were subsidized by the
state (Freedom House, 2014). The new law included well-known religio-
us organizations such as the Hungarian Islamic Council in the category
of ‘religious communities.’ The Hungarian Islamic Council had to lobby
the authorities for a year until it was recognized by the parliament as
78	 Maciej Olejnik	 ŚSP 2 ’19
a church (Molnár, 2012). On the other hand, the Catholic Church and the
Hungarian Reformed Church were treated as churches from the moment
the law was introduced. These religious organizations also turned out to
be effective lobbyists in other aspects of the public sphere. For instance,
they were able to persuade the government to grant higher subsidies to
parish schools than to state schools (Balogh, 2016).
Neither disadvantaged nor privileged interest groups informed the
public about the lobbying activities they conducted. The government
and members of parliament also did not reveal any arguments or reports
which were submitted by organizations that belonged to the disadvan-
taged or privileged groups. Consequently, the effectiveness of lobbying
control did not depend on the status of the interest group that performed
the lobbying activity in Hungary between 2010–2014. The fact that some
minorities were not protected by the law and treated worse than others
was irrelevant to the effectiveness of lobbying control in Hungary.
Conclusions
Five systemic core principles constituting illiberal democracy were
fulfilled in Hungary between 2010–2014. The article shows that four of
them (the rule of law, control over and accountability of the government,
integrity of the political elite and media freedom) adversely affected the
effectiveness of lobbying control conducted in this country.
The Fidesz-KDNP coalition very often breached the rule of law. For
many acts passed by these parties, watchdogs could not determine who
had lobbied public representatives, how they had been lobbied and how
much money the lobbying activities had cost, due to the fact that Hunga-
rian laws lacked stability and explicitness (for instance, the case of the
‘supermarket tax’ act). Therefore, these organizations did not have eno-
ugh time to perform a comprehensive investigation of the interest groups’
role in the process of law-making for many acts, because they were pas-
sed within a couple of days and then changed repeatedly.
Between 2010–2014, the Fidesz-KDNP coalition captured the insti-
tutions that could hold politicians accountable for breaking the law (i.e.
the Supreme Court and the lower courts). Furthermore, the Constitutional
Tribunal’s competences were considerably reduced, so it could not repe-
al specific laws which were clearly unconstitutional, because they favored
a few companies and discriminated against others that operated in the same
ŚSP 2 ’19	 The influence of illiberal democracy on the effectiveness...	 79
branch of the economy. Undoubtedly, the government’s policy with regard
to the judicial system substantially lowered the effectiveness of lobbying
control, because there were no independent controlling institutions that co-
uld force interest groups and the government to reveal information on the
course of their unofficial meetings to the watchdogs. The most crucial po-
litical decisions, including regarding specific laws, were made during these
meetings, but the public did not have access to information on their details
(e.g. what data lobbyists submitted to the government).
The number of corruption practices dramatically increased in Hungary
between 2010–2014, especially with regard to the legislative process and
public procurement contracts. The government always protected politicians
involved in these operations and declined to disclose any specific informa-
tion on the relations between public servants and interest groups, even if
there was a suspicion that a crime had been committed (for instance, the
case of the Tobacco Retailing Act). The public could not access any infor-
mation about the details of illegal lobbying activities, which were growing
in number, from official sources (i.e. public institutions). Without any do-
ubt, the fact that Hungarian political elites were highly corrupt negatively
impacted the effectiveness of attempts to control lobbying.
Since 2011, Hungary has been classified by Freedom House as a state
with only partially free media. This is due mainly to the fact that the vast
majority of media outlets were either captured by the government (the case
of the public media outlets), or were owned by its cronies. It should not be
a surprise that they did not provide any details about lobbying practices
to the public. Neutral media outlets did not want to examine government-
interest groups relations either, because they wanted to sell advertisements
to the biggest Hungarian companies, which mostly belonged either to the
state or the government’s allies. Although there were some opposition me-
dia outlets, they usually did not have enough resources to be able to conduct
investigations into secret lobbying activities. Therefore, it can be claimed
that the public could not count on media outlets to gain information about
interest groups’ role in the process of policy making.
The last systemic criterion constituting illiberal democracy – civil ri-
ghts and the protection of minorities – did not affect the effectiveness of
lobbying control in Hungary, and was in this sense a neutral factor. This
statement is justified by the fact that there was no difference between the
lobbying activities of the privileged and disadvantaged minorities in terms
of their transparency. In both cases, the public knew nothing about the way
in which these groups carried out lobbying actions (how often did they
80	 Maciej Olejnik	 ŚSP 2 ’19
meet with politicians? With whom exactly did they talk? What expertise
did they submit to them?). Neither representatives of these minorities nor
politicians released any information to the public on these matters.
Nevertheless, based on the Hungarian case, it might be argued that
the illiberal model of democracy diminishes the effectiveness of lobbying
control. However, this article should be treated as the beginning of a di-
scussion about possible links between this type of political regime and the
effectiveness of attempts to control lobbying. More studies are needed in
this area of research in order to be able to ascertain that Hungary is not an
exception in this matter.
References
Ágh A., Dieringer J., Bönker F. (2015), 2015 Hungary Report, Bertelsmann Stiftung,
Gütersloh.
Ágh A., Dieringer J., Bönker F. (2016), 2016 Hungary Report, Bertelsmann Stiftung,
Gütersloh.
Alonso S., Keane J., Merkel W. (2011), Editors’introduction: Rethinking the future of
representative democracy, in: The Future of Representative Democracy, eds.
S. Alonso, J. Keane, W. Merkel, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge.
Archives of the Hungarian National Assembly, http://www-archiv.parlament.hu/
angol/append/legislative_act.htm, 01.09.2018.
Armstrong G., Kotler P. (2010), Principles of Marketing, Pearson Education, Lon-
don.
Balogh E., The Hungarian Catholic Church and Education, http://hungarianspectrum.
org/2016/04/01/the-hungarian-catholic-church-and-education/, 01.09.2018.
Bartha A. (2014), Lifting the Lid on Lobbying: National Report of Hungary, Transpar-
ency International Hungary, Budapest.
Bergan D. E. (2009), Does grassroots lobbying work? A field experiment measuring
the effects of an e-mail lobbying campaign on legislative behaviour, “Ameri-
can politics research,” Vol. 37, no. 2.
Dahl R. (2005), Demokracja i jej krytycy, Wydawnictwo Znak, Kraków.
Diamond L. (2002), Consolidating Democracies, in: Comparing Democracies 2: New
Challenges in the Study of Elections and Voting, eds. L. LeDuc, R. Niemi,
P. Norris, SAGE, London.
Dunham J., Nielson B., Aghekyan E. (2015), Freedom of the Press 2015. Harsh Laws
and Violence Drive Global Decline, Freedom House, New York.
Freedom House (2010), Hungary. Freedom in the World 2010, https://freedomhouse.
org/report/freedom-world/2010/hungary, 01.09.2018.
Freedom House (2011), Hungary. Freedom in the World 2011, https://freedomhouse.
org/report/freedom-world/2011/hungary, 01.09.2018.
ŚSP 2 ’19	 The influence of illiberal democracy on the effectiveness...	 81
Freedom House (2014), Hungary. Freedom in the World 2014, https://freedomhouse.
org/report/freedom-world/2014/hungary, 01.09.2018.
Freedom House (2016), Hungary. Freedom in the World 2016, https://freedomhouse.
org/report/freedom-world/2016/hungary, 01.09.2018.
Grant W. (2003a), Lobbyists, in: Concise dictionary of Politics, eds. I. McLean,
A. McMillan, Oxford University Press, Oxford.
Grant W. (2003b), Interest groups, in: Concise dictionary of Politics, eds. I. McLean,
A. McMillan, Oxford University Press, Oxford.
Hegedüs D. (2016) Hungary 2016, Freedom House, New York, https://freedomhouse.
org/sites/default/files/NIT2016_Hungary_0.pdf, 01.09.2018.
Karlekar K. (2010), Freedom of the Press 2010. Broad Setbacks to Global Media
Freedom, Freedom House, New York.
Karlekar K. (2011), Freedom of the Press 2011. Signs of Change Amid Repression,
Freedom House, New York.
Karlekar K., Dunham J. (2012), Freedom of the Press 2012. Breakthroughs and Push-
back in the Middle East, Freedom House, New York.
Karlekar K., Dunham J., Freedom of the Press 2013. Middle East Volatility Amid
Global Decline, Freedom House, New York.
Karlekar K., Dunham J. (2014), Freedom of the Press 2014. Media Freedom Hits
Decade Low, Freedom House, New York.
Karolewski I., Benedikter R. (2017), Europe’s New Rogue States, Poland and Hun-
gary: A Narrative and Its Perspectives, “Chinese Political Science Review,”
no. 2.
Kovács B. (2013), Hungary 2013, in: Nations in Transit 2013: Democratization from
Central Europe to Eurasia, ed. S. Habdank-Kolaczkowska, Rowman and Lit-
tlefield, New York.
Kovács B. (2014), Hungary 2014, in: Nations in Transit 2014: Democratization from
Central Europe to Eurasia, eds. S. Habdank-Kolaczkowska, Z. Csaky, Row-
man and Littlefield, New York.
Kovács B. (2015), Hungary 2015, in: Nations in Transit 2015: Democracy on the
Defensive in Europe and Eurasia, ed. S. Habdank-Kolaczkowska, Rowman
and Littlefield, New York.
Magyar B. (2016), Post-Communist Mafia State: The Case of Hungary, Central Euro-
pean University Press, Budapest.
Merkel W. (2004), Embedded and Defective Democracies, “Democratization,”
vol. 11, no. 5.
Milbrath L. W. (1968), Lobbying, in: International Encyclopedia of the Social Sci-
ences, vol. 9, ed. D. L. Sills, Macmillan Company & the Free Press, United
States of America.
Molnár V., Hungary Expands List of Recognized Churches, http://www.paprikapoli-
tik.com/2012/03/hungary-expands-list-of-recognized-churches/, 01.09.2018.
82	 Maciej Olejnik	 ŚSP 2 ’19
Parvin P. (2007). Friend or foe? Lobbying in British democracy, Hansard Society,
London.
Sánchez-Cuenca I. (2003), Power, Rules, and Compliance, in: Democracy and the
Rule of Law, eds. J. A. Maravall, A. Przeworski, Cambridge University Press,
Cambridge.
Schmitter P. C. (2011), Diagnosis and designing democracy in Europe, in: The Fu-
ture of Representative Democracy, eds. S. Alonso, J. Keane, W. Merkel, Cam-
bridge University Press, Cambridge.
The World Justice Project (2013), Rule of Law Index 2012–2013, The World Justice
Project, Washington DC.
The World Justice Project (2014), Rule of Law Index 2014, The World Justice Project,
Washington DC.
Thomas C. S. (2004), Interests and Interest Groups in the Public Policy Process: (I)
Strategies and Tactics, in: Research Guide to U.S. and International Interest
Groups, ed. C. Thomas, Praeger, Westport.
Wpływ demokracji nieliberalnej na poziom efektywności kontroli
działalności lobbingowej na Węgrzech (2010–2014)
Streszczenie
Zjawisko lobbingu, rozumiane jako wszystkie działania wykonywane przez bądź
w imieniu grup interesu, ukierunkowane na oddziaływanie na proces podejmowania
i implementowania decyzji politycznych, występuje w każdym reżimie politycznym.
W niniejszym artykule zbadano czy nieliberalny model demokracji funkcjonujący na
Węgrzech (2010–2014) wywierał wpływ na poziom efektywności działań mających
na celu kontrolowanie lobbingu. Nieliberalna demokracja różni się od swego liberal-
nego odpowiednika w pięciu obszarach: rządów prawa, kontroli działań rządu i par-
lamentu przez niezależne od władz państwowych instytucje, poziomu korupcji wśród
elit politycznych, stopnia wolności mediów oraz ochrony praw mniejszości. W ar-
tykule wykazano, że Węgry spełniały kryteria demokracji nieliberalnej dla każdego
z obszarów w latach 2010–2014. Na podstawie przeprowadzonych badań stwierdzo-
no, że nieliberalny model demokracji istniejący na Węgrzech zmniejszał efektywność
kontroli działań lobbingowych w tym państwie.
Słowa kluczowe: demokracja nieliberalna, lobbing, Węgry, demokracja liberalna,
rządy prawa
Article submitted: 14.11.2018; article accepted: 07.01.2019.

More Related Content

What's hot

Issues in Policing SAR 2
Issues in Policing SAR 2Issues in Policing SAR 2
Issues in Policing SAR 2Marcos Corley
 
Reforming-the-Philippine-Political-Party-System (1).pdf
Reforming-the-Philippine-Political-Party-System (1).pdfReforming-the-Philippine-Political-Party-System (1).pdf
Reforming-the-Philippine-Political-Party-System (1).pdfRoanmadlangbayan1
 
OECD Forum on Financing Democracy and Averting Policy Capture - Agenda
OECD Forum on Financing Democracy and Averting Policy Capture - AgendaOECD Forum on Financing Democracy and Averting Policy Capture - Agenda
OECD Forum on Financing Democracy and Averting Policy Capture - AgendaOECD Governance
 
En egipto eng Relation Sandro Suzart SUZART GOOGLE INC United States o...
En egipto eng Relation Sandro Suzart  SUZART    GOOGLE INC    United States o...En egipto eng Relation Sandro Suzart  SUZART    GOOGLE INC    United States o...
En egipto eng Relation Sandro Suzart SUZART GOOGLE INC United States o...Sandro Suzart
 
Role of bureaucracy in formulation of foreign policy.
Role of bureaucracy in formulation of foreign policy.Role of bureaucracy in formulation of foreign policy.
Role of bureaucracy in formulation of foreign policy.Tahir Farooq
 
PLCY 340 - UNC-CH 2000 election paper
PLCY 340 - UNC-CH 2000 election paperPLCY 340 - UNC-CH 2000 election paper
PLCY 340 - UNC-CH 2000 election paperZeeshan Haque
 
E-politics from the citizens’ perspective. The role of social networking tool...
E-politics from the citizens’ perspective. The role of social networking tool...E-politics from the citizens’ perspective. The role of social networking tool...
E-politics from the citizens’ perspective. The role of social networking tool...Przegląd Politologiczny
 
Americanpoliticalsystemppt 110919181530-phpapp01
Americanpoliticalsystemppt 110919181530-phpapp01Americanpoliticalsystemppt 110919181530-phpapp01
Americanpoliticalsystemppt 110919181530-phpapp01Wayne Williams
 
online-disinformation-human-rights
online-disinformation-human-rightsonline-disinformation-human-rights
online-disinformation-human-rightsarchiejones4
 
Fines, Leniency, Rewards and Organized Crime: Evidence from Antitrust Experiment
Fines, Leniency, Rewards and Organized Crime: Evidence from Antitrust ExperimentFines, Leniency, Rewards and Organized Crime: Evidence from Antitrust Experiment
Fines, Leniency, Rewards and Organized Crime: Evidence from Antitrust ExperimentStockholm Institute of Transition Economics
 

What's hot (19)

Issues in Policing SAR 2
Issues in Policing SAR 2Issues in Policing SAR 2
Issues in Policing SAR 2
 
Reforming-the-Philippine-Political-Party-System (1).pdf
Reforming-the-Philippine-Political-Party-System (1).pdfReforming-the-Philippine-Political-Party-System (1).pdf
Reforming-the-Philippine-Political-Party-System (1).pdf
 
OECD Forum on Financing Democracy and Averting Policy Capture - Agenda
OECD Forum on Financing Democracy and Averting Policy Capture - AgendaOECD Forum on Financing Democracy and Averting Policy Capture - Agenda
OECD Forum on Financing Democracy and Averting Policy Capture - Agenda
 
En egipto eng Relation Sandro Suzart SUZART GOOGLE INC United States o...
En egipto eng Relation Sandro Suzart  SUZART    GOOGLE INC    United States o...En egipto eng Relation Sandro Suzart  SUZART    GOOGLE INC    United States o...
En egipto eng Relation Sandro Suzart SUZART GOOGLE INC United States o...
 
Trust, Salience and Deterrence
Trust, Salience and DeterrenceTrust, Salience and Deterrence
Trust, Salience and Deterrence
 
Leniency, Asymmetric Punishment and Corruption Evidence from China
Leniency, Asymmetric Punishment and Corruption Evidence from ChinaLeniency, Asymmetric Punishment and Corruption Evidence from China
Leniency, Asymmetric Punishment and Corruption Evidence from China
 
Role of bureaucracy in formulation of foreign policy.
Role of bureaucracy in formulation of foreign policy.Role of bureaucracy in formulation of foreign policy.
Role of bureaucracy in formulation of foreign policy.
 
PLCY 340 - UNC-CH 2000 election paper
PLCY 340 - UNC-CH 2000 election paperPLCY 340 - UNC-CH 2000 election paper
PLCY 340 - UNC-CH 2000 election paper
 
Leniency, Asymmetric Punishment and Corruption: Evidence from China
Leniency, Asymmetric Punishment and Corruption: Evidence from ChinaLeniency, Asymmetric Punishment and Corruption: Evidence from China
Leniency, Asymmetric Punishment and Corruption: Evidence from China
 
What is democracy
What is democracyWhat is democracy
What is democracy
 
E-politics from the citizens’ perspective. The role of social networking tool...
E-politics from the citizens’ perspective. The role of social networking tool...E-politics from the citizens’ perspective. The role of social networking tool...
E-politics from the citizens’ perspective. The role of social networking tool...
 
Americanpoliticalsystemppt 110919181530-phpapp01
Americanpoliticalsystemppt 110919181530-phpapp01Americanpoliticalsystemppt 110919181530-phpapp01
Americanpoliticalsystemppt 110919181530-phpapp01
 
online-disinformation-human-rights
online-disinformation-human-rightsonline-disinformation-human-rights
online-disinformation-human-rights
 
Fines, Leniency, Rewards and Organized Crime: Evidence from Antitrust Experiment
Fines, Leniency, Rewards and Organized Crime: Evidence from Antitrust ExperimentFines, Leniency, Rewards and Organized Crime: Evidence from Antitrust Experiment
Fines, Leniency, Rewards and Organized Crime: Evidence from Antitrust Experiment
 
A0130107
A0130107A0130107
A0130107
 
Pad 510 wk 11 final exam strayer
Pad 510 wk 11 final exam strayerPad 510 wk 11 final exam strayer
Pad 510 wk 11 final exam strayer
 
Government-sponsor Future Centres (3 March 2016)
Government-sponsor Future Centres  (3 March 2016)Government-sponsor Future Centres  (3 March 2016)
Government-sponsor Future Centres (3 March 2016)
 
Article 6
Article 6Article 6
Article 6
 
Theories of Spoils System
Theories of Spoils SystemTheories of Spoils System
Theories of Spoils System
 

Similar to How Illiberal Democracy Diminished Lobbying Control in Hungary

Presentation 2 Democracy
Presentation 2 Democracy Presentation 2 Democracy
Presentation 2 Democracy Keang Choeung
 
Political Development & Civil Society
Political Development & Civil SocietyPolitical Development & Civil Society
Political Development & Civil SocietyChristopher Rice
 
People’s Participation in the Administrative Process
People’s Participation in the Administrative ProcessPeople’s Participation in the Administrative Process
People’s Participation in the Administrative Processinventionjournals
 
Public policy as dividends of democracy
Public policy as dividends of democracyPublic policy as dividends of democracy
Public policy as dividends of democracyAlexander Decker
 
Corruption And Comparative Politics.pdf
Corruption And Comparative Politics.pdfCorruption And Comparative Politics.pdf
Corruption And Comparative Politics.pdfWajidKhanMP
 
Democracy Promotion: unpacking the concept
Democracy Promotion: unpacking the conceptDemocracy Promotion: unpacking the concept
Democracy Promotion: unpacking the conceptMateo Porciúncula
 
MAC 426 Political Communication.docx
MAC 426 Political Communication.docxMAC 426 Political Communication.docx
MAC 426 Political Communication.docxSOMOSCO1
 
EmailPhoneView AuditPrincipal InvestigatorEmai.docx
EmailPhoneView AuditPrincipal InvestigatorEmai.docxEmailPhoneView AuditPrincipal InvestigatorEmai.docx
EmailPhoneView AuditPrincipal InvestigatorEmai.docxSALU18
 
approaches to policy making.pdf
approaches to policy making.pdfapproaches to policy making.pdf
approaches to policy making.pdfJohnRichCaidic
 
Approaches to the study of Public Policy.pdf
Approaches to the study of Public Policy.pdfApproaches to the study of Public Policy.pdf
Approaches to the study of Public Policy.pdfWAQARULLAHZIA1
 
En egipto eng Relation between Sandro Suzart, SUZART, GOOGLE INC, Unite...
En egipto eng Relation between Sandro Suzart,  SUZART,    GOOGLE INC,   Unite...En egipto eng Relation between Sandro Suzart,  SUZART,    GOOGLE INC,   Unite...
En egipto eng Relation between Sandro Suzart, SUZART, GOOGLE INC, Unite...Sandro Santana
 
The Formulation Of Public Policy
The Formulation Of Public PolicyThe Formulation Of Public Policy
The Formulation Of Public PolicyAmy Williams
 
Unlocking Democracy: The Importance of Political Party Registration
Unlocking Democracy: The Importance of Political Party RegistrationUnlocking Democracy: The Importance of Political Party Registration
Unlocking Democracy: The Importance of Political Party RegistrationVakilkaro
 
In a 3 page essay, address the following· Provide a summary of .docx
In a 3 page essay, address the following· Provide a summary of .docxIn a 3 page essay, address the following· Provide a summary of .docx
In a 3 page essay, address the following· Provide a summary of .docxwilcockiris
 
democracy and good governance based on the observation of human rights.
democracy and good governance based on the observation of human rights.democracy and good governance based on the observation of human rights.
democracy and good governance based on the observation of human rights.Wilbert Nyands
 
Democratization, media and elections: Electoral reform in Mexico
Democratization, media and elections:  Electoral reform in MexicoDemocratization, media and elections:  Electoral reform in Mexico
Democratization, media and elections: Electoral reform in MexicoIbero Posgrados
 
27165028 International Business
27165028 International Business27165028 International Business
27165028 International Businessmayank2012
 

Similar to How Illiberal Democracy Diminished Lobbying Control in Hungary (20)

Presentation 2 Democracy
Presentation 2 Democracy Presentation 2 Democracy
Presentation 2 Democracy
 
Political Development & Civil Society
Political Development & Civil SocietyPolitical Development & Civil Society
Political Development & Civil Society
 
People’s Participation in the Administrative Process
People’s Participation in the Administrative ProcessPeople’s Participation in the Administrative Process
People’s Participation in the Administrative Process
 
Public Policy Essay
Public Policy EssayPublic Policy Essay
Public Policy Essay
 
Lobbying
LobbyingLobbying
Lobbying
 
Public policy as dividends of democracy
Public policy as dividends of democracyPublic policy as dividends of democracy
Public policy as dividends of democracy
 
Corruption And Comparative Politics.pdf
Corruption And Comparative Politics.pdfCorruption And Comparative Politics.pdf
Corruption And Comparative Politics.pdf
 
Democracy Promotion: unpacking the concept
Democracy Promotion: unpacking the conceptDemocracy Promotion: unpacking the concept
Democracy Promotion: unpacking the concept
 
MAC 426 Political Communication.docx
MAC 426 Political Communication.docxMAC 426 Political Communication.docx
MAC 426 Political Communication.docx
 
EmailPhoneView AuditPrincipal InvestigatorEmai.docx
EmailPhoneView AuditPrincipal InvestigatorEmai.docxEmailPhoneView AuditPrincipal InvestigatorEmai.docx
EmailPhoneView AuditPrincipal InvestigatorEmai.docx
 
Public Policy Essays
Public Policy EssaysPublic Policy Essays
Public Policy Essays
 
approaches to policy making.pdf
approaches to policy making.pdfapproaches to policy making.pdf
approaches to policy making.pdf
 
Approaches to the study of Public Policy.pdf
Approaches to the study of Public Policy.pdfApproaches to the study of Public Policy.pdf
Approaches to the study of Public Policy.pdf
 
En egipto eng Relation between Sandro Suzart, SUZART, GOOGLE INC, Unite...
En egipto eng Relation between Sandro Suzart,  SUZART,    GOOGLE INC,   Unite...En egipto eng Relation between Sandro Suzart,  SUZART,    GOOGLE INC,   Unite...
En egipto eng Relation between Sandro Suzart, SUZART, GOOGLE INC, Unite...
 
The Formulation Of Public Policy
The Formulation Of Public PolicyThe Formulation Of Public Policy
The Formulation Of Public Policy
 
Unlocking Democracy: The Importance of Political Party Registration
Unlocking Democracy: The Importance of Political Party RegistrationUnlocking Democracy: The Importance of Political Party Registration
Unlocking Democracy: The Importance of Political Party Registration
 
In a 3 page essay, address the following· Provide a summary of .docx
In a 3 page essay, address the following· Provide a summary of .docxIn a 3 page essay, address the following· Provide a summary of .docx
In a 3 page essay, address the following· Provide a summary of .docx
 
democracy and good governance based on the observation of human rights.
democracy and good governance based on the observation of human rights.democracy and good governance based on the observation of human rights.
democracy and good governance based on the observation of human rights.
 
Democratization, media and elections: Electoral reform in Mexico
Democratization, media and elections:  Electoral reform in MexicoDemocratization, media and elections:  Electoral reform in Mexico
Democratization, media and elections: Electoral reform in Mexico
 
27165028 International Business
27165028 International Business27165028 International Business
27165028 International Business
 

More from Środkowoeuropejskie Studia Polityczne

The activity of the Mamy Głos Foundation in the context of youth political a...
The activity of the Mamy Głos Foundation  in the context of youth political a...The activity of the Mamy Głos Foundation  in the context of youth political a...
The activity of the Mamy Głos Foundation in the context of youth political a...Środkowoeuropejskie Studia Polityczne
 
Impact of Brexit on the status of the English language in the European Union
Impact of Brexit on the status of the English  language in the European UnionImpact of Brexit on the status of the English  language in the European Union
Impact of Brexit on the status of the English language in the European UnionŚrodkowoeuropejskie Studia Polityczne
 
Formation of populism in Spain: towards the explanatory framework of the 15-M...
Formation of populism in Spain: towards the explanatory framework of the 15-M...Formation of populism in Spain: towards the explanatory framework of the 15-M...
Formation of populism in Spain: towards the explanatory framework of the 15-M...Środkowoeuropejskie Studia Polityczne
 
Saturation of the media with conspiracy narratives: content analysis of selec...
Saturation of the media with conspiracy narratives: content analysis of selec...Saturation of the media with conspiracy narratives: content analysis of selec...
Saturation of the media with conspiracy narratives: content analysis of selec...Środkowoeuropejskie Studia Polityczne
 
The Rule of Law and the EU Budget for 2021–2027: More Solidarity or Renouncin...
The Rule of Law and the EU Budget for 2021–2027: More Solidarity or Renouncin...The Rule of Law and the EU Budget for 2021–2027: More Solidarity or Renouncin...
The Rule of Law and the EU Budget for 2021–2027: More Solidarity or Renouncin...Środkowoeuropejskie Studia Polityczne
 
International sports organizations as diplomatic actors. The case of FIFA exe...
International sports organizations as diplomatic actors. The case of FIFA exe...International sports organizations as diplomatic actors. The case of FIFA exe...
International sports organizations as diplomatic actors. The case of FIFA exe...Środkowoeuropejskie Studia Polityczne
 
Civil society as an actor in the political processes of local governance refo...
Civil society as an actor in the political processes of local governance refo...Civil society as an actor in the political processes of local governance refo...
Civil society as an actor in the political processes of local governance refo...Środkowoeuropejskie Studia Polityczne
 
Education and information in consumer policy in the Republic of Poland
Education and information in consumer policy  in the Republic of PolandEducation and information in consumer policy  in the Republic of Poland
Education and information in consumer policy in the Republic of PolandŚrodkowoeuropejskie Studia Polityczne
 
Farmland and people as essential resources of Poland in the concepts of Poli...
Farmland and people as essential resources  of Poland in the concepts of Poli...Farmland and people as essential resources  of Poland in the concepts of Poli...
Farmland and people as essential resources of Poland in the concepts of Poli...Środkowoeuropejskie Studia Polityczne
 
The impact of Brexit on the member states’ ability to build blocking coalitio...
The impact of Brexit on the member states’ ability to build blocking coalitio...The impact of Brexit on the member states’ ability to build blocking coalitio...
The impact of Brexit on the member states’ ability to build blocking coalitio...Środkowoeuropejskie Studia Polityczne
 
Dedykowany storytelling – psychologiczne przesłanki perswazyjnej efektywności...
Dedykowany storytelling – psychologiczne przesłanki perswazyjnej efektywności...Dedykowany storytelling – psychologiczne przesłanki perswazyjnej efektywności...
Dedykowany storytelling – psychologiczne przesłanki perswazyjnej efektywności...Środkowoeuropejskie Studia Polityczne
 
Human security, human rights and international law, and interactions between ...
Human security, human rights and international law, and interactions between ...Human security, human rights and international law, and interactions between ...
Human security, human rights and international law, and interactions between ...Środkowoeuropejskie Studia Polityczne
 
Publiczne notowanie akcji jako źródło finansowania małych i średnich przedsię...
Publiczne notowanie akcji jako źródło finansowania małych i średnich przedsię...Publiczne notowanie akcji jako źródło finansowania małych i średnich przedsię...
Publiczne notowanie akcji jako źródło finansowania małych i średnich przedsię...Środkowoeuropejskie Studia Polityczne
 
Polska w strefie euro? Trzy scenariusze i ich prawdopodobne konsekwencje ogól...
Polska w strefie euro? Trzy scenariusze i ich prawdopodobne konsekwencje ogól...Polska w strefie euro? Trzy scenariusze i ich prawdopodobne konsekwencje ogól...
Polska w strefie euro? Trzy scenariusze i ich prawdopodobne konsekwencje ogól...Środkowoeuropejskie Studia Polityczne
 
Próby reformy systemu wyborczego do Rady Najwyższej Ukrainy w okresie przypad...
Próby reformy systemu wyborczego do Rady Najwyższej Ukrainy w okresie przypad...Próby reformy systemu wyborczego do Rady Najwyższej Ukrainy w okresie przypad...
Próby reformy systemu wyborczego do Rady Najwyższej Ukrainy w okresie przypad...Środkowoeuropejskie Studia Polityczne
 
Ustrój samorządu lokalnego w Republice Mołdawii. Ewolucja i stan obecny
Ustrój samorządu lokalnego w Republice Mołdawii. Ewolucja i stan obecnyUstrój samorządu lokalnego w Republice Mołdawii. Ewolucja i stan obecny
Ustrój samorządu lokalnego w Republice Mołdawii. Ewolucja i stan obecnyŚrodkowoeuropejskie Studia Polityczne
 

More from Środkowoeuropejskie Studia Polityczne (20)

The activity of the Mamy Głos Foundation in the context of youth political a...
The activity of the Mamy Głos Foundation  in the context of youth political a...The activity of the Mamy Głos Foundation  in the context of youth political a...
The activity of the Mamy Głos Foundation in the context of youth political a...
 
Impact of Brexit on the status of the English language in the European Union
Impact of Brexit on the status of the English  language in the European UnionImpact of Brexit on the status of the English  language in the European Union
Impact of Brexit on the status of the English language in the European Union
 
Formation of populism in Spain: towards the explanatory framework of the 15-M...
Formation of populism in Spain: towards the explanatory framework of the 15-M...Formation of populism in Spain: towards the explanatory framework of the 15-M...
Formation of populism in Spain: towards the explanatory framework of the 15-M...
 
Non-military dimension of the hybrid war in Ukraine
Non-military dimension of the hybrid war  in UkraineNon-military dimension of the hybrid war  in Ukraine
Non-military dimension of the hybrid war in Ukraine
 
Saturation of the media with conspiracy narratives: content analysis of selec...
Saturation of the media with conspiracy narratives: content analysis of selec...Saturation of the media with conspiracy narratives: content analysis of selec...
Saturation of the media with conspiracy narratives: content analysis of selec...
 
Promotion of regional and traditional products
Promotion of regional and traditional productsPromotion of regional and traditional products
Promotion of regional and traditional products
 
The Rule of Law and the EU Budget for 2021–2027: More Solidarity or Renouncin...
The Rule of Law and the EU Budget for 2021–2027: More Solidarity or Renouncin...The Rule of Law and the EU Budget for 2021–2027: More Solidarity or Renouncin...
The Rule of Law and the EU Budget for 2021–2027: More Solidarity or Renouncin...
 
International sports organizations as diplomatic actors. The case of FIFA exe...
International sports organizations as diplomatic actors. The case of FIFA exe...International sports organizations as diplomatic actors. The case of FIFA exe...
International sports organizations as diplomatic actors. The case of FIFA exe...
 
Civil society as an actor in the political processes of local governance refo...
Civil society as an actor in the political processes of local governance refo...Civil society as an actor in the political processes of local governance refo...
Civil society as an actor in the political processes of local governance refo...
 
Education and information in consumer policy in the Republic of Poland
Education and information in consumer policy  in the Republic of PolandEducation and information in consumer policy  in the Republic of Poland
Education and information in consumer policy in the Republic of Poland
 
Farmland and people as essential resources of Poland in the concepts of Poli...
Farmland and people as essential resources  of Poland in the concepts of Poli...Farmland and people as essential resources  of Poland in the concepts of Poli...
Farmland and people as essential resources of Poland in the concepts of Poli...
 
The impact of Brexit on the member states’ ability to build blocking coalitio...
The impact of Brexit on the member states’ ability to build blocking coalitio...The impact of Brexit on the member states’ ability to build blocking coalitio...
The impact of Brexit on the member states’ ability to build blocking coalitio...
 
Dedykowany storytelling – psychologiczne przesłanki perswazyjnej efektywności...
Dedykowany storytelling – psychologiczne przesłanki perswazyjnej efektywności...Dedykowany storytelling – psychologiczne przesłanki perswazyjnej efektywności...
Dedykowany storytelling – psychologiczne przesłanki perswazyjnej efektywności...
 
Human security, human rights and international law, and interactions between ...
Human security, human rights and international law, and interactions between ...Human security, human rights and international law, and interactions between ...
Human security, human rights and international law, and interactions between ...
 
Publiczne notowanie akcji jako źródło finansowania małych i średnich przedsię...
Publiczne notowanie akcji jako źródło finansowania małych i średnich przedsię...Publiczne notowanie akcji jako źródło finansowania małych i średnich przedsię...
Publiczne notowanie akcji jako źródło finansowania małych i średnich przedsię...
 
Polska w strefie euro? Trzy scenariusze i ich prawdopodobne konsekwencje ogól...
Polska w strefie euro? Trzy scenariusze i ich prawdopodobne konsekwencje ogól...Polska w strefie euro? Trzy scenariusze i ich prawdopodobne konsekwencje ogól...
Polska w strefie euro? Trzy scenariusze i ich prawdopodobne konsekwencje ogól...
 
Trauma transformacji w Europie Środkowo-Wschodniej
Trauma transformacji w Europie Środkowo-WschodniejTrauma transformacji w Europie Środkowo-Wschodniej
Trauma transformacji w Europie Środkowo-Wschodniej
 
Próby reformy systemu wyborczego do Rady Najwyższej Ukrainy w okresie przypad...
Próby reformy systemu wyborczego do Rady Najwyższej Ukrainy w okresie przypad...Próby reformy systemu wyborczego do Rady Najwyższej Ukrainy w okresie przypad...
Próby reformy systemu wyborczego do Rady Najwyższej Ukrainy w okresie przypad...
 
Ustrój samorządu lokalnego w Republice Mołdawii. Ewolucja i stan obecny
Ustrój samorządu lokalnego w Republice Mołdawii. Ewolucja i stan obecnyUstrój samorządu lokalnego w Republice Mołdawii. Ewolucja i stan obecny
Ustrój samorządu lokalnego w Republice Mołdawii. Ewolucja i stan obecny
 
Kształtowanie relacji państwo–diaspora: przykład czarnogórski
Kształtowanie relacji państwo–diaspora: przykład czarnogórskiKształtowanie relacji państwo–diaspora: przykład czarnogórski
Kształtowanie relacji państwo–diaspora: przykład czarnogórski
 

Recently uploaded

Referendum Party 2024 Election Manifesto
Referendum Party 2024 Election ManifestoReferendum Party 2024 Election Manifesto
Referendum Party 2024 Election ManifestoSABC News
 
Opportunities, challenges, and power of media and information
Opportunities, challenges, and power of media and informationOpportunities, challenges, and power of media and information
Opportunities, challenges, and power of media and informationReyMonsales
 
AP Election Survey 2024: TDP-Janasena-BJP Alliance Set To Sweep Victory
AP Election Survey 2024: TDP-Janasena-BJP Alliance Set To Sweep VictoryAP Election Survey 2024: TDP-Janasena-BJP Alliance Set To Sweep Victory
AP Election Survey 2024: TDP-Janasena-BJP Alliance Set To Sweep Victoryanjanibaddipudi1
 
HARNESSING AI FOR ENHANCED MEDIA ANALYSIS A CASE STUDY ON CHATGPT AT DRONE EM...
HARNESSING AI FOR ENHANCED MEDIA ANALYSIS A CASE STUDY ON CHATGPT AT DRONE EM...HARNESSING AI FOR ENHANCED MEDIA ANALYSIS A CASE STUDY ON CHATGPT AT DRONE EM...
HARNESSING AI FOR ENHANCED MEDIA ANALYSIS A CASE STUDY ON CHATGPT AT DRONE EM...Ismail Fahmi
 
Chandrayaan 3 Successful Moon Landing Mission.pdf
Chandrayaan 3 Successful Moon Landing Mission.pdfChandrayaan 3 Successful Moon Landing Mission.pdf
Chandrayaan 3 Successful Moon Landing Mission.pdfauroraaudrey4826
 
Top 10 Wealthiest People In The World.pdf
Top 10 Wealthiest People In The World.pdfTop 10 Wealthiest People In The World.pdf
Top 10 Wealthiest People In The World.pdfauroraaudrey4826
 
Vashi Escorts, {Pooja 09892124323}, Vashi Call Girls
Vashi Escorts, {Pooja 09892124323}, Vashi Call GirlsVashi Escorts, {Pooja 09892124323}, Vashi Call Girls
Vashi Escorts, {Pooja 09892124323}, Vashi Call GirlsPooja Nehwal
 
complaint-ECI-PM-media-1-Chandru.pdfra;;prfk
complaint-ECI-PM-media-1-Chandru.pdfra;;prfkcomplaint-ECI-PM-media-1-Chandru.pdfra;;prfk
complaint-ECI-PM-media-1-Chandru.pdfra;;prfkbhavenpr
 
N Chandrababu Naidu Launches 'Praja Galam' As Part of TDP’s Election Campaign
N Chandrababu Naidu Launches 'Praja Galam' As Part of TDP’s Election CampaignN Chandrababu Naidu Launches 'Praja Galam' As Part of TDP’s Election Campaign
N Chandrababu Naidu Launches 'Praja Galam' As Part of TDP’s Election Campaignanjanibaddipudi1
 
Brief biography of Julius Robert Oppenheimer
Brief biography of Julius Robert OppenheimerBrief biography of Julius Robert Oppenheimer
Brief biography of Julius Robert OppenheimerOmarCabrera39
 
How Europe Underdeveloped Africa_walter.pdf
How Europe Underdeveloped Africa_walter.pdfHow Europe Underdeveloped Africa_walter.pdf
How Europe Underdeveloped Africa_walter.pdfLorenzo Lemes
 
Dynamics of Destructive Polarisation in Mainstream and Social Media: The Case...
Dynamics of Destructive Polarisation in Mainstream and Social Media: The Case...Dynamics of Destructive Polarisation in Mainstream and Social Media: The Case...
Dynamics of Destructive Polarisation in Mainstream and Social Media: The Case...Axel Bruns
 
Manipur-Book-Final-2-compressed.pdfsal'rpk
Manipur-Book-Final-2-compressed.pdfsal'rpkManipur-Book-Final-2-compressed.pdfsal'rpk
Manipur-Book-Final-2-compressed.pdfsal'rpkbhavenpr
 
Different Frontiers of Social Media War in Indonesia Elections 2024
Different Frontiers of Social Media War in Indonesia Elections 2024Different Frontiers of Social Media War in Indonesia Elections 2024
Different Frontiers of Social Media War in Indonesia Elections 2024Ismail Fahmi
 
Quiz for Heritage Indian including all the rounds
Quiz for Heritage Indian including all the roundsQuiz for Heritage Indian including all the rounds
Quiz for Heritage Indian including all the roundsnaxymaxyy
 
VIP Girls Available Call or WhatsApp 9711199012
VIP Girls Available Call or WhatsApp 9711199012VIP Girls Available Call or WhatsApp 9711199012
VIP Girls Available Call or WhatsApp 9711199012ankitnayak356677
 

Recently uploaded (16)

Referendum Party 2024 Election Manifesto
Referendum Party 2024 Election ManifestoReferendum Party 2024 Election Manifesto
Referendum Party 2024 Election Manifesto
 
Opportunities, challenges, and power of media and information
Opportunities, challenges, and power of media and informationOpportunities, challenges, and power of media and information
Opportunities, challenges, and power of media and information
 
AP Election Survey 2024: TDP-Janasena-BJP Alliance Set To Sweep Victory
AP Election Survey 2024: TDP-Janasena-BJP Alliance Set To Sweep VictoryAP Election Survey 2024: TDP-Janasena-BJP Alliance Set To Sweep Victory
AP Election Survey 2024: TDP-Janasena-BJP Alliance Set To Sweep Victory
 
HARNESSING AI FOR ENHANCED MEDIA ANALYSIS A CASE STUDY ON CHATGPT AT DRONE EM...
HARNESSING AI FOR ENHANCED MEDIA ANALYSIS A CASE STUDY ON CHATGPT AT DRONE EM...HARNESSING AI FOR ENHANCED MEDIA ANALYSIS A CASE STUDY ON CHATGPT AT DRONE EM...
HARNESSING AI FOR ENHANCED MEDIA ANALYSIS A CASE STUDY ON CHATGPT AT DRONE EM...
 
Chandrayaan 3 Successful Moon Landing Mission.pdf
Chandrayaan 3 Successful Moon Landing Mission.pdfChandrayaan 3 Successful Moon Landing Mission.pdf
Chandrayaan 3 Successful Moon Landing Mission.pdf
 
Top 10 Wealthiest People In The World.pdf
Top 10 Wealthiest People In The World.pdfTop 10 Wealthiest People In The World.pdf
Top 10 Wealthiest People In The World.pdf
 
Vashi Escorts, {Pooja 09892124323}, Vashi Call Girls
Vashi Escorts, {Pooja 09892124323}, Vashi Call GirlsVashi Escorts, {Pooja 09892124323}, Vashi Call Girls
Vashi Escorts, {Pooja 09892124323}, Vashi Call Girls
 
complaint-ECI-PM-media-1-Chandru.pdfra;;prfk
complaint-ECI-PM-media-1-Chandru.pdfra;;prfkcomplaint-ECI-PM-media-1-Chandru.pdfra;;prfk
complaint-ECI-PM-media-1-Chandru.pdfra;;prfk
 
N Chandrababu Naidu Launches 'Praja Galam' As Part of TDP’s Election Campaign
N Chandrababu Naidu Launches 'Praja Galam' As Part of TDP’s Election CampaignN Chandrababu Naidu Launches 'Praja Galam' As Part of TDP’s Election Campaign
N Chandrababu Naidu Launches 'Praja Galam' As Part of TDP’s Election Campaign
 
Brief biography of Julius Robert Oppenheimer
Brief biography of Julius Robert OppenheimerBrief biography of Julius Robert Oppenheimer
Brief biography of Julius Robert Oppenheimer
 
How Europe Underdeveloped Africa_walter.pdf
How Europe Underdeveloped Africa_walter.pdfHow Europe Underdeveloped Africa_walter.pdf
How Europe Underdeveloped Africa_walter.pdf
 
Dynamics of Destructive Polarisation in Mainstream and Social Media: The Case...
Dynamics of Destructive Polarisation in Mainstream and Social Media: The Case...Dynamics of Destructive Polarisation in Mainstream and Social Media: The Case...
Dynamics of Destructive Polarisation in Mainstream and Social Media: The Case...
 
Manipur-Book-Final-2-compressed.pdfsal'rpk
Manipur-Book-Final-2-compressed.pdfsal'rpkManipur-Book-Final-2-compressed.pdfsal'rpk
Manipur-Book-Final-2-compressed.pdfsal'rpk
 
Different Frontiers of Social Media War in Indonesia Elections 2024
Different Frontiers of Social Media War in Indonesia Elections 2024Different Frontiers of Social Media War in Indonesia Elections 2024
Different Frontiers of Social Media War in Indonesia Elections 2024
 
Quiz for Heritage Indian including all the rounds
Quiz for Heritage Indian including all the roundsQuiz for Heritage Indian including all the rounds
Quiz for Heritage Indian including all the rounds
 
VIP Girls Available Call or WhatsApp 9711199012
VIP Girls Available Call or WhatsApp 9711199012VIP Girls Available Call or WhatsApp 9711199012
VIP Girls Available Call or WhatsApp 9711199012
 

How Illiberal Democracy Diminished Lobbying Control in Hungary

  • 1. DOI 10.14746/ssp.2019.2.4 Maciej Olejnik Centrum Studiów Niemieckich i Europejskich im. Willy’ego Brandta Uniwersytetu Wrocławskiego ORCID: 0000-0002-8697-3158 The influence of illiberal democracy on the effectiveness of attempts to control lobbying in Hungary (2010–2014) Abstract: Lobbying, understood as all actions performed by or on behalf of interest groups directed at influencing of the process of policy formation and implementation, occurs in every political regime. The article examines whether the illiberal type of democracy that exists in Hungary (2010–2014) exerts an influence on the effective- ness of lobbying control.   Illiberal democracy differs from liberal democracy with regard to five systemic core principles, such as the rule of law, government control and accountability, the integrity of political elites, media freedom and civil rights and protection of minorities. This article shows that all of these systemic criteria constituting illiberal democracy were met in Hungary between 2010–2014. Examination of the case of Hungary with regard to lobbying control suggests that illiberal democracy had diminished the effectiveness of lobbying control in this country. Key words: illiberal democracy, lobbying, Hungary, liberal democracy, rule of law Introduction Lobbying occurs in various forms in almost every known political system. Due to the fact that it is almost impossible to eliminate it from the political system, governments, especially in democracies, are interested in devising ways to control lobbying effectively. Lobbying may become a useful tool, which enables members of the parliament and the government to gain knowledge about interest groups’ main problems and find solutions to them. However, there is a risk that citizens will not have the possibility to obtain information about the way in which political de- cisions are made (i.e., how and who is trying to influence the government during the process of policy-making) unless lobbying is regulated effi- ciently. This issue is especially significant in contemporary democratic
  • 2. 66 Maciej Olejnik ŚSP 2 ’19 states, in which the legislative and executive branch of power is elected (directly or indirectly) by the citizens, none of whom should be privileged above others. Democracy can be protected only if the state and interest groups establish clear rules guaranteeing that lobbying organizations are “transparent and accountable and bound by common standards of good practice and ethical conduct” (Parvin, 2007, p. 34). For instance, Philip Parvin indicates that if lobbying is carried out in this way, it can even strengthen “parliamentary democracy, providing new and diverse chan- nels through which different groups and the wider public might feed into the democratic system” (Parvin, 2007, p. 34). There are some significant differences among political and social scientists regarding the definition of lobbying. Gary Armstrong and Phi- lip Kotler argue that lobbying means “building and maintaining relations with legislators and government officials [in order] to influence legisla- tion and regulation” (Armstrong, Kotler, 2010, p. 472). Their definition emphasizes the role of personal relationships that exist between members of parliament or the executive branch and lobbyists. It excludes any gras- sroots action (e.g. email campaigns, demonstrations) from the sphere of lobbying. In contrast, Wyn Grant perceives lobbying as a wider phenome- non: “Lobbying refers to attempts to exert influence on the formation or implementation of public policy” (Grant, 2003a, p. 314). This interpreta- tion assumes that lobbying activities include all kinds of relations betwe- en lobbyists and authorities, as well as other actions in which members of the latter group are not directly involved, such as demonstrations, strikes, and television and internet campaigns. Wyn Grant’s definition seems to be better suited to modern democratic states than Gary Armstrong and Philip Kotler’s concept. Of course, many political decisions are still reached during meetings between lobbyists and the authorities. However, bottom- up actions through which lobbyists try to influence authorities also often end successfully. For instance, Daniel Bergan’s experiment conducted on the members of the New Hampshire state legislature confirmed this. The result of this research shows that email lobbying campaigns substantially influenced legislators’ voting behavior (Bergen, 2009, pp. 327–352). Political and social scientists have some difficulties in identifying who actually performs lobbying activity. Clive Thomas and Ronald Hrebenar created one of the broadest classifications, distinguishing five groups of lobbyists: contract lobbyists; in-house lobbyists; government legislative liaisons; citizen, cause or volunteer lobbyists; and private individuals, ‘hobbyists’ or self-appointed lobbyists (Thomas, 2004, pp. 152–153).
  • 3. ŚSP 2 ’19 The influence of illiberal democracy on the effectiveness... 67 Lobbyists from the first four groups always act on behalf of someone else (e.g. corporations, companies and local governments which employ them, or non-profit organizations). Members of the last group “lobby for pet projects, direct personal benefits or against a policy or proposal they find particularly objectionable” (Thomas, 2004, p. 153). Lester Milbrath pre- sented a different approach to this issue. In this perspective, every attempt at impacting the government’s political decisions should be treated as an example of lobbying if it is carried out “by someone other than a citizen acting on his own behalf” (Milbrath, 1968, p. 442). From this point of view, a person who tries to achieve their political interests individually by influencing the government should not be treated as a lobbyist. This might be a very reasonable position, as it seems virtually impossible to effectively analyze lobbying if we consider people who undertake any po- litical action in their own political interest (such as criticizing government decisions that directly affect them on Facebook) to be lobbyists. For the purpose of this article, I consider lobbyists to be only those entities which try to affect authorities’ political decisions on behalf of interest groups. Wyn Grant defines interest groups as “organizations seeking to advance a particular sectional interest or cause while not seeking to form a go- vernment or part of a government” (Grant, 2003b, p. 266). This definition embraces non-profit associations, trade unions, companies and any other institution that is even partially involved in the process of policy-making unless it also tries to formally gain power in the country. In the latter part of the article, the term ‘lobbying’ refers to all actions performed by or on behalf of interest groups directed at the influencing the process of policy formation and implementation. One of the most crucial aspects of studies on lobbying relates to its ef- fective control. Lobbying is effectively controlled if it is completely trans- parent, which means that the public have easy access to the following in- formation: “(a) who is lobbying public representatives, (b) on what issues they are being lobbied, (c) when and how they are being lobbied, (d) how much is being spent in the process, (e) what is the result of these lobbying efforts?” (Bartha, 2014, p. 7), and the authorities cannot refuse to share this information with the public. Four out of five systemic core principles that constitute liberal democracy enhance the effectiveness of lobbying control in the state. These features include: the government following the rule of law, especially with regard to the stability, explicitness and gene- ral and prospective nature of passed laws; the existence of completely independent institutions which can verify whether the government is fol-
  • 4. 68 Maciej Olejnik ŚSP 2 ’19 lowing the rule of law, as well as repeal any unconstitutional laws; low levels of corruption among political elites, which discourages interests groups from illegally influencing politicians’ decisions (i.e. bribery); and fully free, autonomous media outlets which are critical of the government and are capable of investigating ties between the government and interest groups. These systemic core principles allow the legislative process to be conducted in an entirely transparent way. The fifth principle – civil rights and protection of minorities – is not a meaningful factor affecting the effectiveness of lobbying control. Against this backdrop, the aim of this article is to examine whether the illiberal model of democracy in Hungary influenced the effectiveness of attempts to control lobbying between 2010–2014, or whether it was irrelevant in this regard. Within this period of time, Hungary transfor- med from a liberal to an illiberal democracy. I argue that the worsening quality of democracy in illiberal democracies, mainly with regard to the rule of law, the takeover of previously independent oversight institutions by the ruling political parties, the considerable rise in corruption practi- ces among members of the government, and the partial decline of media freedom may also have consequences on the effectiveness of lobbying control. Thus, I suggest the following hypothesis: the illiberal model of democracy exerts a negative influence on the effectiveness of lobbying control in Hungary. The Hungarian example was examined because there is a predominant opinion in academic discourse that, since 2010, Hungary has rejected the path of socio-political development towards liberal democracy, choosing its illiberal version instead (Karolewski, Benedikter, 2017, pp. 179–180, 184–185). Analysis of the Hungarian case study will be treated as an in- troduction to a discussion of the possible correlation between the illiberal model of democracy and the effectiveness of lobbying control worldwide. This analysis is innovative as no research showing this type of correlation seems to exist. Systemic criteria constituting liberal and illiberal democracy Democracy has radically changed over the centuries in terms of its size, scale and scope (Schmitter, 2011, pp. 191–192), as well as with re- gard to many further aspects (Schmitter, 2011, pp. 193–198). Currently, a country is identified as democratic only if some guarantees are anchored
  • 5. ŚSP 2 ’19 The influence of illiberal democracy on the effectiveness... 69 institutionally, in particular free, regular and competitive elections, fre- edom of association, freedom of speech and access to various, alternative sources of information (Dahl’s concept of full polyarchy) (Dahl, 2005, p. 332). We can distinguish two types of democracy (liberal and illiberal democracy) that fulfill all elements of full polyarchy. They operate dif- ferently with regard to the five systemic core principles (the rule of law, government control and accountability, integrity of political elites, media freedom and civil rights and protection of minorities). The first distinction between liberal and illiberal democracy concerns the rule of law. In this article, the term is defined as “compliance with the law, when the law is general, public, prospective, clear, consistent, performable, and stable” (Sánchez-Cuenca, 2003, p. 69). In the illiberal democratic country, laws are not constructed and implemented according to those principles. Moreover, in illiberal democracies, the government often does not follow the rule of law unless it suits the interests of the power elite. Conversely, in liberal democracies the rule of law is applied in most of the cases. Rare violations of the rule of law also occur in libe- ral democracies, but such situations take place considerably less often in liberal than illiberal democracies. The second difference concerns con- trol over government actions and accountability. In liberal democracies, there are independent institutions (e.g. the Constitutional Tribunal, the Supreme Court or the lower courts), which can convict politicians even if they belong to the ruling elite and repeal government policies if they are illegal. Furthermore, these decisions are respected and implemented by the government or other public institutions. In illiberal democratic co- untries, the government either does not recognize unfavorable decisions or subjugates these institutions according to their preferences (Merkel, 2004, p. 49). The third distinction refers to the level of corruption. It is high in illibe- ral democracies (Alonso, Keane, Merkel, 2011, p. 11), while political elites are corrupt to the lesser extent in liberal democratic states. However, there are no countries in which this kind of misuse of power has been completely eliminated, even among the highly transparent and accountable elites of the Scandinavian countries. This is why the criteria of media freedom – the fo- urth dissimilarity between the analyzed political regimes – are so crucial for the survival of a liberal democracy. Liberal democracies are characterized by fully free media. It is often media outlets that reveal corrupt practices among the authorities in liberal democratic states. Media activity can lead to a politician’s fall from grace and even to convictions in liberal democra-
  • 6. 70 Maciej Olejnik ŚSP 2 ’19 cies. The media are only partially free in the illiberal democracy (Alonso, Keane, Merkel, 2011, p. 11). A significant number of them are controlled by the ruling political parties or their allies. Nevertheless, there are a few influential media outlets which are independent and try to monitor the go- vernment’s activity. This is one of the crucial differences between illiberal democracies and authoritarian systems. The fifth difference between liberal and illiberal democracy involves civil rights and the state’s policies regarding minorities. In illiberal demo- cratic countries, civil rights are often partially suspended (Merkel, 2004, p. 49), and minorities are also exposed to discrimination. On the other hand, civil rights function flawlessly in the liberal democracies, in parti- cular due to the independent system of courts. Liberal democracies pro- tect minorities and guarantee their “right to speak their languages, prac- tice their culture and express their identities” (Diamond, 2002, p. 213). Table 1 summarizes the comparative analysis of liberal and illiberal de- mocracy through the prism of areas differentiating these political regimes (cf. Alonso, Keane, Merkel, 2011, p. 11). Table 1 Discrepancies between the systemic criteria constituting liberal and illiberal democracies Areas of differen- tiation between liberal and illib- eral democracy Systemic criteria constituting liberal democracy Systemic criteria constituting illiberal democracy 1 2 3 The rule of law The government usually fol- lows the rule of law. The government often breaches the rule of law if it is in its political inter- est to do so. Government con- trol and account- ability There are institutions in- dependent from the gov- ernment, which can hold political elites accountable and have the right to repeal their unlawful policies. The government recognizes all decisions made by the inde- pendent institutions. The government is not de facto over- seen by any institution. The govern- ment rejects implementing decisions taken by oversight bodies which are unfavorable to it. These institutions are deprived of the majority of their competences or are captured by the ruling political elites soon after they form the government. Integrity of politi- cal elites Political elites are corrupt to a small extent Corrupt political elites Media freedom Free and independent media Majority of media controlled by the government or its allies
  • 7. ŚSP 2 ’19 The influence of illiberal democracy on the effectiveness... 71 1 2 3 Civil rights and protection of mi- norities Citizens can benefit from civil right law. Minorities’ rights are protected by the law. Some rights are suspended or abol- ished. Minorities are exposed to dis- crimination and are not protected by the law. Source: Own compilation based on S. Alonso, J. Keane, W. Merkel, Editors’ introduc- tion: Rethinking the future of representative democracy, in: The Future of Representative Democracy, eds. S. Alonso, J. Keane, W. Merkel, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge 2011, pp. 1–22; W. Merkel, Embedded and Defective Democracies, “Democratization,” vol. 11, no. 5, December 2004, pp. 33–58. Illiberal democracy’s influence on lobbying control in Hungary Based on the comparative analysis of liberal and illiberal democracy presented in this article, Hungary was part of the latter group of political systems between 2010–2014. Five systemic criteria constituting illiberal democracy were fulfilled in Hungary in this period of time. The second government of Viktor Orbán (2010–2014) formed by the Hungarian Civic Alliance (Fidesz) and the Christian Democratic People’s Party (KDNP), which achieved a 2/3 majority in the parliamentary elec- tions in 2010 (Magyar, 2016, p. 15), allowing parties to change the con- stitution without the opposition’s consent, did not follow the rule of law (Magyar, 2016, p. 289). In 2010, the Hungarian parliament repealed the only law (The Lobbying Act) that comprehensively regulated lobbying in Hungary (Bartha, 2014, p. 8), and since then has passed many laws which were inconsistent with the rule of law. Some of these had a retroactive effect, e.g. the law which obliged judges to retire at the age of 62 (it repla- ced the act that allowed judges to serve until the age of 70) came into for- ce without any transition period and also applied to judges who exceeded this age before the act was adopted. In this way, hundreds of judges were suddenly forced into retirement (Kovács, 2015, p. 283). Between 2010–2014, the Hungarian parliament passed not only gene- ral, but also many specific laws which aimed to enable corporations and companies tied to the government to strengthen their position in the sector of the economy within which they operated. New laws contained regula- tions which supported selected companies against their competitors. Two laws introducing an extra tax on financial institutions and imposing a new tax on supermarkets are good illustrations of such practices. In the former case, the new legislation imposed a tax on all insurance companies except
  • 8. 72 Maciej Olejnik ŚSP 2 ’19 for those founded between 2007–2010. However, it turned out that there was only one considerable insurance company (CIG) set up in this period of time that could have taken advantage of the new law. It belonged to Járai Zsigmond – a close associate of Prime Minister Viktor Orbán. Járai Zsigmond was a Minister of Finance in his first government which was in power between 1998–2002 (Bartha, 2014, pp. 29–30). The latter legisla- tion set a tax that applied to all supermarket chains operating in Hungary apart from the one (CBA) whose owners had close relations with mem- bers of the government (Bartha, 2014, p. 29). Any attempts to successfully control lobbying activity during the pro- cess of law-making were ineffective due to the fact that, since 2010, Hun- garian law has lacked other crucial features constituting the rule of law: stability and explicitness. Even the most significant legal act in Hungary – a new constitution that came into force in 2012 – was substantially changed five times within three years (Kovács, 2015, p. 273). Further- more, “the degree of legal uncertainty is also indicated by the unprece- dentedly large number of acts (859) and amendments (538) passed during the second Orbán government” (Ágh, Dieringer, Bönker, 2015, p. 16) (the Hungarian parliament passed significantly fewer laws in its previous terms; 587 between 2006–2010, 573 between 2002–2006 and 460 betwe- en 1998–2002 [Archives of the Hungarian National Assembly, 2014]). Many of these were presented to the public, proceeded and adopted by the parliament within only one day, preventing any substantial debate on the issue. For instance, the most crucial amendments to the ‘supermarket tax’ act have been passed that way (Bartha, 2014, p. 29). Moreover, due to the fact that the law regulating access to public information turned out to be very imprecise, it is extremely difficult and sometimes impossible to gain any information regarding lobbyists’role in the process of policy-making, even after the new law has been implemented. In 2010–2014, this law has been changed many times (Kovács, 2015, p. 284, Hegedüs, 2016, p. 9) so public institutions could take advantage of various vague provisions and loopholes and refuse to release information concerning the process of policy-making to the public. Undoubtedly, the fact that Hungarian law was not stable and was not created in an explicit way affected the effectiveness of lobbying control substantially, especially with regard to such issues as who actually per- formed lobbying activity, as well as what methods were applied and how much money was spent. This is corroborated by the fact that even in- stitutions (e.g. watchdogs) interested in examining whether any lobbyist
  • 9. ŚSP 2 ’19 The influence of illiberal democracy on the effectiveness... 73 influenced the legislative process were unable to do so, because the speed of the political decision-making was too fast to allow any meaningful oversight. The process of creating specific laws should have been sub- ject to close scrutiny, because their aim was to grant some companies an operating advantage in a particular branch of the economy. It is therefore no wonder that many interest groups attempted to influence the content of these projects. Unfortunately, specific laws were not only proceeded in the shortest possible time, but they were also frequently altered, so it was impossible to find out how lobbying was carried out for these acts (for in- stance, when and how members of the government were lobbied). Taking those facts into consideration leads to the conclusion that considerable deficiencies in the rule of law in Hungary diminished the effectiveness of lobbying control in this country. Since 2010, there have been no institutions in Hungary which could effectively control the government’s activity, including relations betwe- en its members and lobbyists. The Constitutional Tribunal attempted to be such an institution in terms of law-making, especially during the first three years of Viktor Orbán’s second government. For instance, in 2010 the Tribunal repealed the law that retroactively imposed a 98% tax on severance pay in the public sector between 2005–2010 (Freedom House, 2011). However, the government, instead of honoring this ruling – as all former governments had – reintroduced the same tax after the parliament substantially slashed the Constitutional Tribunal’s competences. Within four years, the Tribunal lost the majority of its competences, which left it impotent in terms of effective judicial review. For instance, unless new laws threaten citizens’ fundamental rights, the Constitutional Tribunal is no longer allowed to examine cases related to the public budget (Ko- vács, 2013, p. 261). This means that the Tribunal cannot verify whether laws imposing new taxes on various branches of the economy are consi- stent with the constitution, even if they directly favor specific companies and thus constitute discrimination. Since April 2013, the majority of the Constitutional Tribunal’s members have been nominated by Fidesz and KDNP. From then on, all government decisions questioned by the oppo- sition and non-governmental organizations have been ruled in favor of the government (Hegedüs, 2016, pp. 8–9). Also, the judicial system has been captured by the power elite. In particular, judges who had strong ties with the ruling political parties were appointed to both lower courts and the Supreme Court between 2010–2014. The lower courts made some deci- sions which went against the government’s political interests, but in case
  • 10. 74 Maciej Olejnik ŚSP 2 ’19 of the Supreme Court nearly all rulings were beneficial to the government (Ágh, Dieringer, Bönker, 2015, pp. 16–17). Public officials, aware of the fact that they would not be punished for breaking the law, sometimes deli- berately delayed the implementation of courts’ decisions propitious to the government’s opponents (Hegedüs, 2016, p. 10). Overall, it has produced a political system in which the ruling parties can not only pass every law without any negative legal consequences, but also forged an alliance between the government and the companies owned either by the political elite’s family members and cronies or employing them. As a result, these companies support Fidesz and KDNP (i.e. via financing media favorable to the government and refusing to buy advertisements in opposition media outlets). During the frequent meetings between members of this alliance, representatives of the companies influenced the government’s political decisions on many crucial socio-economic matters, which were then im- plemented within next couple of days (Bartha, 2014, p. 20). Neither po- liticians nor representatives of the companies shared with the public any information concerning the course of these meetings, the lobbyists’ aims or information submitted to decision-makers. In the majority of cases, the public could not obtain any information about the process of policy-making that took place between the mem- bers of the government and lobbyists during their meetings, because there were no truly independent institutions which might force politicians to reveal them, or convict these people if they refused to do so. Thus, it can be stated that the effectiveness of lobbying control in Hungary was negatively influenced by the fact that, in practice, not only can members of the government not be held accountable or their decisions monitored, but illiberal democracy in Hungary fostered collusion between the state and some enterprises. Against this backdrop, corruption has become a significant problem in Hungary in terms of policy formation and implementation. While interest groups initiate corrupt practices in the majority of democratic countries, in Hungary it was the government that was mainly responsible for the promotion of corruption. The government decided who would belong to this politico-economic alliance, which had a corrupt nature. Within this system, the coalition of ruling political parties used “its legislative power to interfere with even minor segments of the economy and benefit its private-sector clients” (Kovács, 2015, p. 286). A new law regulating the trade in tobacco products is one striking example of this phenomenon. In April 2013, the Fidesz-KDNP coalition passed the Tobacco Retailing
  • 11. ŚSP 2 ’19 The influence of illiberal democracy on the effectiveness... 75 Act, which reduced the number of tobacco retail licenses from 40,000 to 5000 and redistributed them almost exclusively among companies that had close ties with the members of the government. A couple of mon- ths later, it introduced amendments to this law enabling companies that possessed the license to remarkably increase their revenues. Journalists accidentally discovered that one of the versions of the Tobacco Retailing Act was prepared on the laptop of the CEO of a Hungarian tobacco com- pany, János Sánta, which then obtained more than 10% of licenses. The government admitted that János Sánta was involved in the legislation pro- cess but it did not explain what the nature of his engagement was (e.g. which members of the government did this person meet? What data and expertise did he provide?) (Bartha, 2014, pp. 30–31). Consequently, the public knew nothing about the way in which lobbying was carried out in the case of the Tobacco Retailing Act. Citizens could only be certain that the government’s allies took advantage of the new law. There were many more cases of corruption concerning public procurement contracts, as well as further corruption scandals between 2010–2014 (Hegedüs, 2016, p. 10). There was a lack of transparency in the relations between lobbyists and the government, and no attempts to enhance transparency were made from either side. Thus, it should not be a surprise that Hungary obtained a worse score (it was very low even before 2010) in studies on corruption in 2014 than in the previous years, conducted by international organiza- tions such as the World Justice Project (The World Justice Project, 2013, p. 97; The World Justice Project, 2014, p. 100) and Freedom House (He- gedüs, 2016, p. 1). Corrupt politicians frequently tried to conceal compromising details on their unofficial ties with interest groups from the public. Even when watchdogs obtained a little information on secret lobbying practices (as happened in case of the Tobacco Retailing Act), members of the Hun- garian government did not provide any further details about them. They were afraid that this information might discredit them and cause a loss in their parties’ popularity. Thus, the public were deprived of any specifics on uncontrolled lobbying, particularly with regard to the way in which lobbying activities were carried out and the amount of money that was involved in these practices. Undoubtedly, the fact that political elites were corrupt to a very large extent notably reduced the effectiveness of lobby- ing control in Hungary. Freedom House has examined the media’s status in Hungary since 2002. Until 2010, it was rated as ‘free’ (Karlekar, 2010, p. 15; Karlekar
  • 12. 76 Maciej Olejnik ŚSP 2 ’19 2011, p. 14). The score declined after the formation of the second Orbán government. Since 2011, every year the media’s status in Hungary has been described as ‘partially free’ by Freedom House (Karlekar, Dunham, 2012, p. 15; Karlekar, Dunham, 2013, p. 14; Karlekar, Dunham, 2014, p. 20; Dunham, Nelson, Aghekyan, 2015, p. 22). This assessment is com- pletely justified for several reasons. Firstly, the public media were taken over by the government in 2010, and since then they have served as state propaganda outlets (Kovács, 2013, p. 257). Even in the private sector, the majority of newspapers, magazines, online news outlets and one of two most powerful private television channels belong to companies that are allied with the government (e.g., TV2, Metropol, Helyi Téma, Magyar Nemzet [Bartha, 2014, p. 24; Kovács, 2015, p. 280]). They provide the public solely with news and commentary that is favorable to the govern- ment. Still, other powerful television channels, as well as some online news outlets, remained neutral in Hungary throughout the second Orbán government (e.g., RTL Klub, Origo.hu [Bartha, 2014, pp. 24–25; Kovács, 2015, p. 279]) but there were few opposition media outlets in this country between 2010–2014 (e.g., Klubrádió, Népszabadság [Bartha, 2014, p. 24; Kovács, 2014, 270]). Also, journalists restrained themselves in reporting news that might be interpreted as hurting the government politically or le- gally. This was caused by the fear of losing advertising revenue, which in Hungary mainly comes from the state or companies allied with the ruling parties. Between 2010–2014, opposition media outlets lost this source of income to pro-government media. Journalists were also afraid that the Media Council1 would impose considerable fines on the companies they worked for if they revealed information that could be unfavorable to the government. Unsurprisingly, the vast majority of the media outlets did not under- take any serious attempts to examine how lobbying was carried out in Hungary in this political environment. Pro-government media outlets did not want to do this because they supported Fidesz and KDNP. Any cor- 1   The Media Council is an administrative organ of the National Media and In- focommunications Authority, which is a regulatory body that “oversees all media, public and private, including broadcast, print, and online outlets” (Kovács, “Hungary in 2015”, p. 281). The Media Council has the right to impose significant fines for activities that are very difficult to define, such as inciting hatred against majorities. Al- though the Media Council is formally an autonomous institution, in fact it is strongly biased in favor of the ruling parties as only government loyalists have been nominated to this institution by the parliament.
  • 13. ŚSP 2 ’19 The influence of illiberal democracy on the effectiveness... 77 ruption scandals, including those involving lobbying activity, could cause the government to lose popularity and thus power. In turn, this would al- most certainly mean also the loss of revenue for these media outlets, since state-owned companies controlled by the current opposition would not buy advertisements in these outlets. While the ‘neutral’ media abstained from closely investigating specific relations between the government and its allied companies, because they also wanted to sell advertisements to them, the opposition media did not have enough resources to be able to carefully examine lobbying activities. The role of the media is to investigate various lobbying practices and disclose information about them to the society if public institutions let citizens down in this matter. However, in the majority of cases, the Hun- garian media either did not want to or were not able to discover who the lobbyists that tried to influence the government’s policy were, how they did this and what were the results of their actions. Without any doubt, the lack of complete media freedom diminished the effectiveness of lobbying control in Hungary. Hungary did not fully protect civil rights or minorities from discrimina- tion even before Orbán formed his second government in 2010 (Freedom House, 2010), but these problems deepened significantly afterwards. Al- though the Romani people constitute by far the largest ethnic minority in Hungary (about 5–7% of Hungarians), they have few representatives in the parliament and have long been treated as ‘second-class citizens,’ e.g. many Romani children were put into schools for children with mental di- sabilities (Freedom House, 2014).This population also suffered from ha- rassment and hate speech, which usually did not meet with the proper re- sponse from the public institutions (Ágh, Dieringer, Bönker, 2016, p. 16). The LGBT community was another minority facing similar problems, as the police and members of the government were among the groups that were responsible for harassing LGBT people (Freedom House, 2016). Various religious groups have also been treated unequally in Hungary. In 2011, the Hungarian parliament passed the law on the legal status of churches, which divided religious organizations into two types: religious communities (90% of religious organizations belong to this group) and churches. Only organizations from the latter group were subsidized by the state (Freedom House, 2014). The new law included well-known religio- us organizations such as the Hungarian Islamic Council in the category of ‘religious communities.’ The Hungarian Islamic Council had to lobby the authorities for a year until it was recognized by the parliament as
  • 14. 78 Maciej Olejnik ŚSP 2 ’19 a church (Molnár, 2012). On the other hand, the Catholic Church and the Hungarian Reformed Church were treated as churches from the moment the law was introduced. These religious organizations also turned out to be effective lobbyists in other aspects of the public sphere. For instance, they were able to persuade the government to grant higher subsidies to parish schools than to state schools (Balogh, 2016). Neither disadvantaged nor privileged interest groups informed the public about the lobbying activities they conducted. The government and members of parliament also did not reveal any arguments or reports which were submitted by organizations that belonged to the disadvan- taged or privileged groups. Consequently, the effectiveness of lobbying control did not depend on the status of the interest group that performed the lobbying activity in Hungary between 2010–2014. The fact that some minorities were not protected by the law and treated worse than others was irrelevant to the effectiveness of lobbying control in Hungary. Conclusions Five systemic core principles constituting illiberal democracy were fulfilled in Hungary between 2010–2014. The article shows that four of them (the rule of law, control over and accountability of the government, integrity of the political elite and media freedom) adversely affected the effectiveness of lobbying control conducted in this country. The Fidesz-KDNP coalition very often breached the rule of law. For many acts passed by these parties, watchdogs could not determine who had lobbied public representatives, how they had been lobbied and how much money the lobbying activities had cost, due to the fact that Hunga- rian laws lacked stability and explicitness (for instance, the case of the ‘supermarket tax’ act). Therefore, these organizations did not have eno- ugh time to perform a comprehensive investigation of the interest groups’ role in the process of law-making for many acts, because they were pas- sed within a couple of days and then changed repeatedly. Between 2010–2014, the Fidesz-KDNP coalition captured the insti- tutions that could hold politicians accountable for breaking the law (i.e. the Supreme Court and the lower courts). Furthermore, the Constitutional Tribunal’s competences were considerably reduced, so it could not repe- al specific laws which were clearly unconstitutional, because they favored a few companies and discriminated against others that operated in the same
  • 15. ŚSP 2 ’19 The influence of illiberal democracy on the effectiveness... 79 branch of the economy. Undoubtedly, the government’s policy with regard to the judicial system substantially lowered the effectiveness of lobbying control, because there were no independent controlling institutions that co- uld force interest groups and the government to reveal information on the course of their unofficial meetings to the watchdogs. The most crucial po- litical decisions, including regarding specific laws, were made during these meetings, but the public did not have access to information on their details (e.g. what data lobbyists submitted to the government). The number of corruption practices dramatically increased in Hungary between 2010–2014, especially with regard to the legislative process and public procurement contracts. The government always protected politicians involved in these operations and declined to disclose any specific informa- tion on the relations between public servants and interest groups, even if there was a suspicion that a crime had been committed (for instance, the case of the Tobacco Retailing Act). The public could not access any infor- mation about the details of illegal lobbying activities, which were growing in number, from official sources (i.e. public institutions). Without any do- ubt, the fact that Hungarian political elites were highly corrupt negatively impacted the effectiveness of attempts to control lobbying. Since 2011, Hungary has been classified by Freedom House as a state with only partially free media. This is due mainly to the fact that the vast majority of media outlets were either captured by the government (the case of the public media outlets), or were owned by its cronies. It should not be a surprise that they did not provide any details about lobbying practices to the public. Neutral media outlets did not want to examine government- interest groups relations either, because they wanted to sell advertisements to the biggest Hungarian companies, which mostly belonged either to the state or the government’s allies. Although there were some opposition me- dia outlets, they usually did not have enough resources to be able to conduct investigations into secret lobbying activities. Therefore, it can be claimed that the public could not count on media outlets to gain information about interest groups’ role in the process of policy making. The last systemic criterion constituting illiberal democracy – civil ri- ghts and the protection of minorities – did not affect the effectiveness of lobbying control in Hungary, and was in this sense a neutral factor. This statement is justified by the fact that there was no difference between the lobbying activities of the privileged and disadvantaged minorities in terms of their transparency. In both cases, the public knew nothing about the way in which these groups carried out lobbying actions (how often did they
  • 16. 80 Maciej Olejnik ŚSP 2 ’19 meet with politicians? With whom exactly did they talk? What expertise did they submit to them?). Neither representatives of these minorities nor politicians released any information to the public on these matters. Nevertheless, based on the Hungarian case, it might be argued that the illiberal model of democracy diminishes the effectiveness of lobbying control. However, this article should be treated as the beginning of a di- scussion about possible links between this type of political regime and the effectiveness of attempts to control lobbying. More studies are needed in this area of research in order to be able to ascertain that Hungary is not an exception in this matter. References Ágh A., Dieringer J., Bönker F. (2015), 2015 Hungary Report, Bertelsmann Stiftung, Gütersloh. Ágh A., Dieringer J., Bönker F. (2016), 2016 Hungary Report, Bertelsmann Stiftung, Gütersloh. Alonso S., Keane J., Merkel W. (2011), Editors’introduction: Rethinking the future of representative democracy, in: The Future of Representative Democracy, eds. S. Alonso, J. Keane, W. Merkel, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge. Archives of the Hungarian National Assembly, http://www-archiv.parlament.hu/ angol/append/legislative_act.htm, 01.09.2018. Armstrong G., Kotler P. (2010), Principles of Marketing, Pearson Education, Lon- don. Balogh E., The Hungarian Catholic Church and Education, http://hungarianspectrum. org/2016/04/01/the-hungarian-catholic-church-and-education/, 01.09.2018. Bartha A. (2014), Lifting the Lid on Lobbying: National Report of Hungary, Transpar- ency International Hungary, Budapest. Bergan D. E. (2009), Does grassroots lobbying work? A field experiment measuring the effects of an e-mail lobbying campaign on legislative behaviour, “Ameri- can politics research,” Vol. 37, no. 2. Dahl R. (2005), Demokracja i jej krytycy, Wydawnictwo Znak, Kraków. Diamond L. (2002), Consolidating Democracies, in: Comparing Democracies 2: New Challenges in the Study of Elections and Voting, eds. L. LeDuc, R. Niemi, P. Norris, SAGE, London. Dunham J., Nielson B., Aghekyan E. (2015), Freedom of the Press 2015. Harsh Laws and Violence Drive Global Decline, Freedom House, New York. Freedom House (2010), Hungary. Freedom in the World 2010, https://freedomhouse. org/report/freedom-world/2010/hungary, 01.09.2018. Freedom House (2011), Hungary. Freedom in the World 2011, https://freedomhouse. org/report/freedom-world/2011/hungary, 01.09.2018.
  • 17. ŚSP 2 ’19 The influence of illiberal democracy on the effectiveness... 81 Freedom House (2014), Hungary. Freedom in the World 2014, https://freedomhouse. org/report/freedom-world/2014/hungary, 01.09.2018. Freedom House (2016), Hungary. Freedom in the World 2016, https://freedomhouse. org/report/freedom-world/2016/hungary, 01.09.2018. Grant W. (2003a), Lobbyists, in: Concise dictionary of Politics, eds. I. McLean, A. McMillan, Oxford University Press, Oxford. Grant W. (2003b), Interest groups, in: Concise dictionary of Politics, eds. I. McLean, A. McMillan, Oxford University Press, Oxford. Hegedüs D. (2016) Hungary 2016, Freedom House, New York, https://freedomhouse. org/sites/default/files/NIT2016_Hungary_0.pdf, 01.09.2018. Karlekar K. (2010), Freedom of the Press 2010. Broad Setbacks to Global Media Freedom, Freedom House, New York. Karlekar K. (2011), Freedom of the Press 2011. Signs of Change Amid Repression, Freedom House, New York. Karlekar K., Dunham J. (2012), Freedom of the Press 2012. Breakthroughs and Push- back in the Middle East, Freedom House, New York. Karlekar K., Dunham J., Freedom of the Press 2013. Middle East Volatility Amid Global Decline, Freedom House, New York. Karlekar K., Dunham J. (2014), Freedom of the Press 2014. Media Freedom Hits Decade Low, Freedom House, New York. Karolewski I., Benedikter R. (2017), Europe’s New Rogue States, Poland and Hun- gary: A Narrative and Its Perspectives, “Chinese Political Science Review,” no. 2. Kovács B. (2013), Hungary 2013, in: Nations in Transit 2013: Democratization from Central Europe to Eurasia, ed. S. Habdank-Kolaczkowska, Rowman and Lit- tlefield, New York. Kovács B. (2014), Hungary 2014, in: Nations in Transit 2014: Democratization from Central Europe to Eurasia, eds. S. Habdank-Kolaczkowska, Z. Csaky, Row- man and Littlefield, New York. Kovács B. (2015), Hungary 2015, in: Nations in Transit 2015: Democracy on the Defensive in Europe and Eurasia, ed. S. Habdank-Kolaczkowska, Rowman and Littlefield, New York. Magyar B. (2016), Post-Communist Mafia State: The Case of Hungary, Central Euro- pean University Press, Budapest. Merkel W. (2004), Embedded and Defective Democracies, “Democratization,” vol. 11, no. 5. Milbrath L. W. (1968), Lobbying, in: International Encyclopedia of the Social Sci- ences, vol. 9, ed. D. L. Sills, Macmillan Company & the Free Press, United States of America. Molnár V., Hungary Expands List of Recognized Churches, http://www.paprikapoli- tik.com/2012/03/hungary-expands-list-of-recognized-churches/, 01.09.2018.
  • 18. 82 Maciej Olejnik ŚSP 2 ’19 Parvin P. (2007). Friend or foe? Lobbying in British democracy, Hansard Society, London. Sánchez-Cuenca I. (2003), Power, Rules, and Compliance, in: Democracy and the Rule of Law, eds. J. A. Maravall, A. Przeworski, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge. Schmitter P. C. (2011), Diagnosis and designing democracy in Europe, in: The Fu- ture of Representative Democracy, eds. S. Alonso, J. Keane, W. Merkel, Cam- bridge University Press, Cambridge. The World Justice Project (2013), Rule of Law Index 2012–2013, The World Justice Project, Washington DC. The World Justice Project (2014), Rule of Law Index 2014, The World Justice Project, Washington DC. Thomas C. S. (2004), Interests and Interest Groups in the Public Policy Process: (I) Strategies and Tactics, in: Research Guide to U.S. and International Interest Groups, ed. C. Thomas, Praeger, Westport. Wpływ demokracji nieliberalnej na poziom efektywności kontroli działalności lobbingowej na Węgrzech (2010–2014) Streszczenie Zjawisko lobbingu, rozumiane jako wszystkie działania wykonywane przez bądź w imieniu grup interesu, ukierunkowane na oddziaływanie na proces podejmowania i implementowania decyzji politycznych, występuje w każdym reżimie politycznym. W niniejszym artykule zbadano czy nieliberalny model demokracji funkcjonujący na Węgrzech (2010–2014) wywierał wpływ na poziom efektywności działań mających na celu kontrolowanie lobbingu. Nieliberalna demokracja różni się od swego liberal- nego odpowiednika w pięciu obszarach: rządów prawa, kontroli działań rządu i par- lamentu przez niezależne od władz państwowych instytucje, poziomu korupcji wśród elit politycznych, stopnia wolności mediów oraz ochrony praw mniejszości. W ar- tykule wykazano, że Węgry spełniały kryteria demokracji nieliberalnej dla każdego z obszarów w latach 2010–2014. Na podstawie przeprowadzonych badań stwierdzo- no, że nieliberalny model demokracji istniejący na Węgrzech zmniejszał efektywność kontroli działań lobbingowych w tym państwie. Słowa kluczowe: demokracja nieliberalna, lobbing, Węgry, demokracja liberalna, rządy prawa Article submitted: 14.11.2018; article accepted: 07.01.2019.