SlideShare a Scribd company logo
1 of 22
Download to read offline
Info Systems J 
(2005) 
15 
, 321–341 
© 2005 Blackwell Publishing Ltd 
321 
Blackwell Science, LtdOxford, UKISJInformation Systems Journal1350-1917Blackwell Publishing Ltd, 200515 
321341 
Original Article 
Business relationships in electronic marketsR Bunduchi 
Business relationships in internet-based 
electronic markets: the role of goodwill trust 
and transaction costs 
Raluca Bunduchi 
Research Centre for Social Sciences, University of Edinburgh, Edinburgh EH1 1LZ, 
Scotland, email: bunduchi@yahoo.com 
Abstract. 
Transaction costs and goodwill trust, which differentiate between trans-actional 
and collaborative relationships, were found in existing research to play a 
significant role in the way organizations use internet technologies to manage their 
relationships with customers and suppliers within electronic markets (EM). How-ever, 
a thorough investigation of role that the two dimensions play together in shap-ing 
the use of EM is lacking from the mainstream literature. This research 
addresses transaction costs and goodwill trust together to clarify the transforma-tions 
that internet use has brought on the nature of interorganizational relation-ships 
that develop between EM players. The research finds the use of EM in 
collaborative relationships is governed by trade-offs between different outcomes 
that different EM functionalities have on organizational objectives. Organizations 
assess these trade-offs, and select those functionalities that best serve to achieve 
their collaborative relational objectives. In contrast, no trade-offs are find in the 
transactional model, as the use of EM here is driven principally by transaction cost 
reductions. 
Keywords: 
electronic markets, inter-organizational relationships, transaction cost 
economics, trust 
1 
. 
INTRODUCTION 
Some of the first researchers to study the consequences that the use of information technology 
(IT) has on the nature of buyer–seller relationships are Malone, Yates and Benjamin in their 
seminal article 
Electronic markets and electronic hierarchies 
(Malone 
et al 
., 1987). The authors 
apply the transaction cost economics (TCE) framework and show that IT use lowers transaction 
costs and favours arms-length relationships between economic actors. Following TCE-based 
research led to contradictory results regarding the outcome of IT use: Clemons 
et al 
.’s (1993) 
study finds that IT use favours collaborative relationships, whereas Hart and Estrin’s (1991) 
study suggests that IT use creates incentives for organizations to internalize their activities.
R Bunduchi 
© 2005 Blackwell Publishing Ltd, 
Information Systems Journal 
15 
, 321–341 
322 
A reason for these divergent results is that different types of IT applications can be used 
to support different types of relationships (Gallivan & Depledge, 2003; Garcia-Dastugue & 
Lambert, 2003). Organizational research differentiates between two types of buyer–seller rela-tionships: 
transactional or arms-length relationships, and collaborative or obligational relation-ships. 
The former are characterized by low interdependence, short-term commitment, 
prearranged terms and conditions in a written contract, narrow communication channels, low 
trust and low asset specificity. In contrast, the latter are characterized by strong interde-pendences, 
high levels of trust and commitment, long-term span, high transaction costs, terms 
and conditions loosely specified and high asset specificity (Sako, 1992; Morgan & Hunt, 1994; 
Dyer 
et al 
., 1998; Lambe 
et al 
., 2001). Transactional relationships can be seen as economic 
exchanges, concerned with the economic exchange of goods and/or services between parties, 
whereas collaborative relationships involve economic as well as social exchanges such as 
interdependencies, friendships, closeness and trust (Smith Ring & Van de Ven, 1994; Back-haus 
& Buschken, 1997; Easton, 1997). As an economic theory, TCE fails to account for social 
exchanges such as trust and power, which are considered irrelevant to the study of economic 
exchanges (Williamson, 1993). Therefore, while TCE studies can explain for the outcome of IT 
use in transactional relationships, they are limited in their ability to account for collaborative 
outcomes of IT. 
This study addresses a particular type of internet-enabled application, internet-based elec-tronic 
markets (EM). This article follows Christiaanse 
et al 
. (2004) in defining EM as 
‘electronic 
networks where buyers and sellers meet to engage in buying and selling as well as other activ-ities, 
such as collaborative planning, logistics, transportation arrangements and fulfilment’ 
(p. 
152). Such a definition acknowledges that EM are not limited to a matter of buying and selling 
(Bakos, 1991), but may also support a range of other functionalities such as supply chain man-agement 
solutions, fulfilment and trust mechanisms (Christiaanse 
et al 
., 2004). 
Depending on their core functionality, Markus & Christiaanse (2003) differentiate between 
transactional and collaborative EM. Transactional EM provide mainly commerce functional-ities, 
such as auctions and electronic billing, which enable members to conduct transactions, 
whereas collaborative EM focus on functionalities which facilitate collaboration, such as 
shared databases and inventory management. Both types might also provide content func-tionality 
that does not generate cash flow, but enhance the EM’s core functionality, such as 
discussions forums and event calendar. The authors argue that transactional EM can be seen 
as purchasing intermediaries between buyers and sellers and can be analysed within the TCE 
framework. In contrast, the TCE approach fails to account for the impact of collaborative EM, 
whose core functionality is processes facilitation, not necessarily the mediation of purchasing 
transactions. 
Consequently, the TCE framework alone is inadequate to fully explain for the outcome of EM 
use on interorganizational relationships (Kumar & Dissel, 1996; Kraut 
et al 
., 1998; Kumar 
et al 
., 
1998; Christiaanse & Kumar, 2000; Markus & Christiaanse, 2003). Markus & Christiaanse 
(2003) suggests that different analytical frameworks are required to address the integration 
effect of collaborative EM, and the role of power and pre-existing relationships between actors. 
Kraut 
et al 
. (1998) and Kumar 
et al 
. (1998) argue that collaboration relational characteristics
Business relationships in electronic markets 
© 2005 Blackwell Publishing Ltd, 
Information Systems Journal 
15 
, 321–341 
323 
such as trust should be included in the TCE analysis to address EM use in collaborative 
relationships. 
This article follows the latter recommendations and analyses the collaborative and transac-tional 
use of IT in relationships between buyers and sellers through addressing transaction cost 
and goodwill trust. The article is structured as follows: section 2 discusses the theoretical foun-dations 
of the study and clarifies the transaction costs and trust concepts. The research meth-odology 
is presented in section 3. Section 4 describes the role that trust and transaction costs 
play in explaining the nature of business relationships between EM players in two case studies. 
The research conclusions, limitations and future research are discussed in section 5. 
2 
. 
BACKGROUND 
: 
TRANSACTION 
COSTS 
, 
TRUST 
AND 
EM 
2.1. Transaction cost economics-based approaches 
Research regarding the role of IT in shaping the nature of interorganizational relationships has 
predominantly adopted a TCE stance. The reason is that TCE explains such relationships in 
terms of transaction costs, where these transaction costs are directly related to IT use (Malone 
et al 
., 1987). 
According to TCE, organizations choose between alternative types of business exchanges 
based on the level of transaction costs (Williamson, 1986). Collaborative exchanges are pre-ferred 
when transaction costs are high, whereas transactional exchanges are preferred when 
transaction costs are low (Clemons 
et al 
., 1993). Transaction costs are seen as the crucial vari-able 
influencing the nature of interorganizational relationships. 
Transaction cost economics literature differentiates between two categories of transaction 
costs aspects: 
1 
Transaction costs – defined as 
‘the costs of exchanging information and incorporating that 
information into decision processes, as well as the costs incurred by the firm due to delays in 
the communication channel’ 
(Clemons 
et al 
., 1993, p. 15). 
2 
Transaction risks – defined as 
‘the cost associated with the exposure to being exploited in 
the relationships’ 
(Kumar & van Dissel, 1996, p. 292) include operation and opportunism risks. 
a. Operation risks are 
‘the risks that the other parties in the transaction wilfully misrepresent 
or withhold information, or underperform – that is “skink” – their agreed-upon responsi-bilities’ 
(Clemons 
et al 
., 1993, p. 15). The existence of high operation risks requires orga-nizations 
to closely control and monitor the exchange. 
b. Opportunism risks are 
‘the risks associated with a lack of bargaining power or the loss of 
bargaining power directly resulting from the execution of a relationship, that is, a differ-ence 
between ex ante and ex post bargaining power’ 
(Clemons 
et al 
., 1993, p. 16). High 
asset specificity, few potential partners and loss of resource control as a result of the 
exchange generate opportunism risks. 
It is generally assumed in the literature that IT use reduces transaction costs. Malone 
et al 
. 
(1987) argue that IT use reduces the time and cost of communication, decreases the costs of
R Bunduchi 
© 2005 Blackwell Publishing Ltd, 
Information Systems Journal 
15 
, 321–341 
324 
the product selection process, and allows for a tighter coupling of information processes that 
increases the speed, reduces the errors, and allows for better linkages between the buyers and 
suppliers’ information systems (IS) which lower transaction costs. This outcome is confirmed 
in following studies. Bakos (1991; 1998) finds that searching costs are lower within EM, Hart 
& Estrin (1991) note that IT use improves coordination, while Clemons 
et al 
. (1993) argue that 
IT use reduces the costs of explicit coordination. 
As according to the TCE framework, lower transaction costs lead to higher reliance on trans-actional 
exchanges, some researchers argued that EM use facilitates the development of 
transactional relationships between EM players (Malone 
et al 
., 1987). However, following stud-ies 
find that IT use enables more efficient control through better information flow, whereas 
higher reliance on open standards reduces the idiosyncrasy of IT investments which translate 
in lower operation and opportunism risks (Clemons 
et al 
., 1993). As these risks are higher in 
collaborative relationships, it means that as EM use reduces transaction risks, organizations 
have more incentives for collaboration. Following studies confirmed that EM relationships tend 
to be collaborative in nature (Steinfield 
et al 
., 1995; Bakos & Brynjolfsson, 1997; Christiaanse 
& Kumar, 2000). 
Not all empirical research confirms this collaborative effect of IT use. Hart & Estrin (1991) 
find that EM development is associated with high vulnerability costs such as 
‘the costs of 
adopting specialized procedures, erosion of control over internally generated information’ 
(p. 
376). These vulnerability costs are manifestations of what Clemons 
et al 
. (1993) call oppor-tunism 
risks, i.e. loss of control resulting from specialized investments. Geun Lee & Clark 
(1996/97) find that EM lead to higher uncertainties as buyers face the risks of incomplete and 
distorted information, and sellers face the possibility that their offers will not be appropriately 
valued in an unproved market system. These uncertainties translate in higher opportunism 
risks, that obstructs EM adoption (Geun Lee & Clark, 1996/97) and encourages internalization 
of activities (Hart & Estrin, 1991). 
Figure 1 summarizes these different findings. 
Different explanations are advanced in the literature to justify for the different outcomes of 
EM use. They include organizational objectives (Garcia-Dastugue & Lambert, 2003), supply 
chain characteristics (Christiaanse & Kumar, 2000), and the inability of the TCE framework to 
account for the integration effects, the history of pre-existing relationships (Markus & Chris-tiaanse, 
2003), and the trust and interpersonal relationships between EM players (Steinfield 
et al 
., 1995; Kraut 
et al 
., 1998; Kumar 
et al 
., 1998; Christiaanse & Kumar, 2000). This article 
focuses on the latter explanation and addresses the role of trust in shaping the use of EM in 
buyer–seller relationships. 
2.2. Beyond economic exchanges: trust and EM 
Existing research defines trust as a critical characteristic of collaborative interorganizational 
relationship (Morgan & Hunt, 1994; Zaheer 
et al 
., 1998; Lambe 
et al 
., 2001). However, TCE 
conceptualizes business relationships in terms of transactions between economic actors, char-acterized 
by opportunistic behaviour, that is calculative self-interest. In this context, trust is
Business relationships in electronic markets 
Information 
technologies 
Figure 1. 
Transaction costs and risks, and electronic markets (EM). 
© 2005 Blackwell Publishing Ltd, 
Information Systems Journal 
15 
, 321–341 
325 
‘warranted when the expected gain from placing oneself at risk is positive, but not otherwise’ 
(Williamson, 1993, p. 463) and is described as a subclass of risk. Trust based on faith in the 
other actors is considered irrelevant to the study of economic exchanges. However, trust was 
found as a critical concept to influence the development of interorganizational relationships in 
a number of organizational studies (Sako, 1992; Smith Ring & Van de Ven, 1992; 1994; Morgan 
& Hunt, 1994; Zaheer 
et al 
., 1998) 
The literature provides two general conceptualizations of trust: risk-based trust, defined as 
confidence in one’s expectations about another’s behaviour; and goodwill trust, understood as 
confidence in another’s goodwill (Smith Ring & Van de Ven, 1994; Nooteboom, 1996; Pavlou, 
2002). The risk-based perspective on trust acknowledges that parties will employ formal con-tracts 
to hedge against the uncertainty in the relationship, whereas the goodwill perspective 
emphasizes the role that interpersonal interactions between organizations play in dealing with 
this uncertainty. Such interpersonal relationships create faith in the moral integrity of the other 
party that she will not take advantage of the relationship (Smith Ring & Van de Ven, 1994). 
This research follows Nooteboom (1996) and Smith Ring & Van de Ven (1992) in addressing 
the role that goodwill trust has in understanding the nature interorganizational relationships. 
Goodwill trust can be defined at two levels (Zaheer 
et al 
., 1998): 
1 
personal level – trust between individuals. 
2 
organizational level – trust between organizations. 
Transaction 
risks 
Transaction 
costs 
Transaction 
risks 
Collaborative 
relationships 
(Bakos & Brynjolfsson, 1997; 
Christiaanse & Kumar, 2000; 
Competitive 
relationships 
(Malone et al., 1987) 
Barriers for EM 
adoption 
& internalisation 
(Hart & Estrin, 1991; 
Geun Lee & Clark, 1996/97) 
Efficient control, 
Better information flow, 
Open standards 
Increase communication speed, 
Reduce communication costs 
Reduce the costs of searching 
for and selection of products 
Increase speed, reduce errors, 
Improve the linkages between 
partners informational systems 
Adoption of specialised procedures, 
Erosion of control over internally 
generated information 
(Hart & Estrin, 1991) 
Incomplete and distorted information 
and unproven market systems which 
increase uncertainties 
(Geun Lee & Clark, 1996/97) 
– 
– 
+ 
(Clemons et al., 1993) 
(Clemons et al., 1993; Malone et al., 1987) 
(Clemons et al., 1993; Malone et al., 1987) 
(Malone et al., 1987) 
Clemons et al., 1993) 
Steinfield et al., 1995)
R Bunduchi 
© 2005 Blackwell Publishing Ltd, 
Information Systems Journal 
15 
, 321–341 
326 
By its nature, trust is defined at the personal level, however, individuals in an organization may 
‘share an orientation toward another organisation’ 
(Zaheer 
et al 
., 1998, p. 143). The two levels 
are closely interrelated: 
• 
As individuals enact the relationship between organizations, their personal relations become 
part of the interorganizational relationship (Gulati 
et al 
., 2000), and; 
• 
Interpersonal relations are conditioned by the legal systems and organizational role respon-sibilities 
that characterize relationships between organizations (Smith Ring & Van de Ven, 
1994). 
Triggered by the limitations identified in the TCE framework to deal with the social aspects 
of IT use (Kumar 
et al 
., 1998), as well as by the increasing focus in organizational research in 
the role that trust plays in shaping interorganizational relationships (Pavlou, 2002; Gallivan & 
Depledge, 2003), a number of studies have begun to address the role that trust, and in par-ticular 
goodwill trust, plays in the context of EM relationships. 
In general, existing research converges on the belief that EM affects significantly the level of 
trust between the actors involved (Luo, 2002; Gallivan & Depledge, 2003), although only few 
such studies differentiate between goodwill and risk-based trust (Pavlou, 2002; Ratmasingam, 
2005). Specific institutional mechanisms such as cooperation norms and accreditation were 
found to support goodwill organizational trust in internet-based EM (Luo, 2002; Pavlou, 2002). 
Luo (2002) argues that EM also sustains personal trust through online communities and other 
linkages between strategically allied companies. Security services such as confidentiality and 
authentication mechanisms embedded in EM are also shown to support goodwill (Ratmasin-gam, 
2005) interorganizational trust development (Srinivasan, 2004). Based on an extensive 
analysis of existing studies regarding the relation between IT use and trust in interorganiza-tional 
relationships, Gallivan & Depledge (2003) conclude that the use of such technologies 
can enhance trust between EM players, but such outcome depends on the type of IT func-tionalities 
used. The study suggests that whereas open sharing of confidential information sus-tains 
trust development, one-sided information flow, e.g. (i.e. monitoring the other party), leads 
to low levels of trust. 
Trust was also shown to influence IT use (Meier, 1995; Hart & Saunders, 1998). Hart and 
Saunders’ study (1998) finds that trust alleviates the risks that the other party will take advan-tage 
of the information exchanged in the relationships. Soliman & Janz (2004) find that with the 
advent of internet, trust remains a significant variable influencing the adoption and use of inter-organizational 
systems. Such a finding is confirmed in other studies that find that organizations 
are more likely to engage in internet-based exchanges with trusted parties (Vlosky 
et al 
., 
2000). However, none of these studies differentiate between the various types of trust. 
In conclusion, trust literature argues that there is a two-way relation between trust and 
EM use, although it is not always clear which type of trust do the findings refer to (Gallivan 
& Depledge, 2003). As trust supports collaborative relationship (Lambe 
et al 
., 2001), it 
appears that collaboration is a prerequisite for EM use, and can be reinforced through the 
use of such technologies. Based on existing literature, this argument is summarized in 
Figure 2.
Business relationships in electronic markets 
TR US T 
(Cooperative norms, 
accreditation, feedback) 
(Luo, 2002; Pavlou, 2002) 
Online communities; 
linkages between 
allied organisations 
(Luo, 2002) 
(reduces Depledge 
vulnerability) 
In fo rmatio n 
(Hart & Saunders, 
te c hno lo gi es 
1998; Meier, 1995; 
Soliman & Janz, 2004; 
Vlosky et al., 2000) 
In st itutio na l me chanis ms 
Open info rmation sharin g 
( Ga lliv an & D epl ed ge, 20 03 ) 
One si de d inform at io n flow 
Figure 2. 
Trust and the use of electronic markets. 
Se cu ri ty se rv ic es 
( Ra tn as i nga m , 20 05 ; 
Sr in iva sa n , 2 00 4 ) 
TR US T 
+ 
– 
( Ga lliv an & D epl ed ge, 20 03 ) TR US T 
© 2005 Blackwell Publishing Ltd, 
Information Systems Journal 
15 
, 321–341 
327 
Co lla borativ e 
re la tions hi ps 
( Ga lliv an & , 2003 ) 
Co mp et it iv e 
re la tions hi ps 
( Ga lliv an & Depledge , 2003 ) 
Existing research suggests that both transaction costs and trust play a significant role for the 
way EM are used between buyers and sellers. However, whereas some TCE-based studies 
suggest that goodwill trust has to be included into the analysis to clarify the outcomes of EM 
on the nature of interorganizational relationships (Kumar 
et al 
., 1998; Christiaanse & Kumar, 
2000), there are no empirical studies in the mainstream literature that address these dimen-sions 
together. Moreover, research on trust in EM, with a few exceptions (Pavlou, 2002), does 
not differentiate explicitly between goodwill and risk-based trust, and even then, it does not 
address the personal and organizational dimensions together. 
This research addresses the role that transaction costs and goodwill trust have in explaining 
the outcomes of IT use on the nature of relationships developed among EM players. The 
research methodology that guided the empirical research is discussed in the next section. 
3 
. 
RESEARCH 
METHOD 
The empirical research follows a qualitative multi-case study research design. The choice was 
based on the following rationales.
R Bunduchi 
© 2005 Blackwell Publishing Ltd, 
Information Systems Journal 
15 
, 321–341 
328 
First, the notion of ‘trust’ is multi-dimensional and difficult to measure, leading to its different 
conceptualizations in IS empirical studies (Gallivan & Depledge, 2002). As case studies focus 
on in-depth analysis (Stake, 1995), they enable the researcher to explore the complexity of the 
‘trust’ concept. Second, this research understands technology as a social construct (Russell & 
Williams, 2002) shaped by the organizational context in which it is used (Ngwenyama & Lee, 
1997). Case study design approaches enable the researcher to capture and understand the 
social and organizational context in which the phenomenon – the use of EM – occurs (Hussey 
& Hussey, 1997). Finally, following Stake (1995), the focus of this research is to search for hap-penings 
and not occurrences. The thrust of the study is to understand the phenomenon – the 
use of EM in relation to transaction costs and trust – without necessarily looking for the sta-tistical 
representation of the findings. This focus influences both the ontology of the research 
as the phenomenon cannot be abstracted from the subjective interpretations of the people who 
experienced them, and the research epistemology as the researcher sees herself as part of the 
social constructed reality, and believes that understanding the meanings that participants place 
on their experiences requires interactive discussions between herself and the participants. 
Qualitative case studies fulfil both requirements, as approach reality as socially constructed by 
the people involved (Creswell, 1994), and enables the researcher to interact with the respon-dents 
to capture their meanings and experiences (Stake, 1995). 
One of the common critiques of the qualitative case study design is the extent to which the 
findings are generalizable to populations or universes (Yin, 1994). Two arguments against this 
critique are explored here. First, case studies are generalizable to theoretical propositions and 
not to populations in the sense that case studies do not (aim to) represent a ‘sample’ of the total 
population. The aim of the investigator is to understand a particular issue (Stake, 1995), and 
not to enumerate instances in which a particular theory holds true (Yin, 1994). Second, often 
quantitative approaches are themselves unable to explain the limits to the domain of gener-alizability 
from their empirical findings. Russell & Williams (2002), e.g. argue that large-scale 
surveys can run to risk to inappropriately group different phenomena on the basis of features 
that are not necessarily the most significant. 
Two unrelated organizations are included into the study, as shown in Table 1: 
The selection of the cases follows the intensity criteria (Miles & Huberman, 1994). At the time 
of the study, internet-based EM were relatively a recent phenomenon and their use is not wide- 
Table 1. 
Overview of cases 
Characteristics OrgA OrgB 
Industry Petroleum Energy 
Role Consultancy Multi-utility 
Size Large Large 
Respondents Strategic Architect (SA); Customer 
Web team member (CW); Manager 
in Organizational Development (MOO) 
Supply Chain Manager (SCM), 
General Manager (GM), Product Manager 
(PrdM), IT consultant (ITC), 
Director of System Integration (DSI)
Business relationships in electronic markets 
Table 2. 
Interview guide and research objectives 
Interview guide Research objective 
What are the key internet applications used to support customers 
and/or suppliers relationships? 
Identify the use and key functionalities of the 
EM. 
Are they used to the same extent with all types of partners? Explain 
the differences. Are there different levels of using these 
technologies in terms of access, amount of information, 
customization? 
Identify the characteristics of EM applications. 
Explain how/if their use varies depending on 
the characteristics of business relationships. 
What are the reasons for the existence of these differences? 
Are such differences related to interpersonal relationships, 
confidence in the other party, communication costs, or the risks 
involved in the transaction? 
Which are the main advantages/disadvantages in using the EM 
applications? Are these related to trust, cost reductions or 
transaction risks? 
Identify the outcomes of the use of EM 
applications on the level of trust, transaction 
costs and risks. 
EM, electronic market. 
© 2005 Blackwell Publishing Ltd, 
Information Systems Journal 
15 
, 321–341 
329 
spread (Leek 
et al 
., 2003). It was assumed that leading companies would have not only the 
financial resources to acquire such technologies, but also that the expectations of their part-ners 
regarding EM adoption will be higher for them. Therefore, the cases were selected among 
the leading organizations in their industries assuming that in such cases EM usage would be 
most intensive, thereby providing rich information. 
Data collection was based on semi-structured interviews complemented with documenta-tion, 
which, following Remenyi 
et al 
. (2000), was primarily used to set the context for the inter-views. 
The interview guide followed a loose structured format, with open-ended questions that 
were intended to stimulate the respondents to reflect on their experiences in using the EM 
across different partners. The questions were mapped onto the research objectives, as shown 
in Table 2. 
Data validation was ensured through next day respondent validation, and through data tri-angulation. 
The information obtained during the interviews was checked, where possible, with 
the data gathered through documentation, and with the data provided by other interviewees. 
As this study seeks to combine two theoretical insights (TCE and trust) rather than to focus 
on the description of a case, ‘relying on a theoretical proposition’ was chosen as the strategy 
for data analysis. Data analysis begun gradually as the interviews proceeded. The approach 
allowed for a gradual refinement of the interview guide as new relevant topics appeared during 
the analysis and of the list of codes as the tentative conclusions were tested against new evi-dence 
(Miles & Huberman, 1994; Stake, 1995). 
Categorical aggregation (Stake, 1995), or what is called ‘open coding’ in grounded theory 
(Strauss & Corbin, 1990), was used to reduce the data. Coding started with a provisional list 
of codes created prior to the fieldwork based on the literature review. These codes are labels 
attached to chunks of data from the interviews, which serve to assign units of meaning to the 
information compiled during the study (Miles & Huberman, 1994). The initial list included two
R Bunduchi 
© 2005 Blackwell Publishing Ltd, Information Systems Journal 15, 321–341 
330 
broad categories: (1) concepts regarding EM applications such as extent of use and type of 
exchange, and (2) concepts concerning the nature of relationships such as personal and orga-nizational 
trust, communication and coordination costs, operation risks and opportunism risks. 
Based on these codes, descriptive data displays were generated to explore the relation 
between EM use and the nature of interorganizational relationships. For example, conceptual 
clustered matrix were developed to explore the linkages between EM use and the nature of 
interorganizational relationships. Table 3 described one such matrix developed to map the out-comes 
of EM use on transaction costs and trust for OrgA. 
Such descriptive matrix displays served two purposes. First, they allowed an in-depth explo-ration 
of the phenomenon (the relation between EM usage and the level of trust and transaction 
costs). Second, displaying the data in a structured and organized fashion helped the 
researcher to better comprehend the phenomenon. Based on this improved understanding, the 
researcher was able to gradually refine the list of codes. For example, the level of customiza-tion 
of the EM applications was added to the EM concepts category as it recurrently appeared 
to reflect different usages of EM in different types of relationships. 
Table 3. Conceptual clustered matrix illustration 
EM 
outcomes/type of 
relationship 
Bronze (low 
transaction costs, 
organization trust 
present) 
Silver (medium transaction costs 
and organizational trust) 
Gold (high transaction costs and 
organizational trust) 
Transaction costs Replace offline with 
online interaction (–) 
Replace offline with online 
interaction (–) 
Replace offline with online interaction 
(–) 
The registration and 
administration of EM 
applications is done by the 
client, not by OrgB (–) 
The registration and administration of 
EM applications is done by the client, 
not by OrgB (–) 
EM applications are highly customized 
to the gold customers’ requirements 
(+) 
Transaction risks None None High customization of EM applications 
increases customers’ switching costs, 
and improves OrgB’s bargaining 
position (–) 
Organizational 
trust 
None EM applications support 
confidential information 
exchange with the customer (+) 
EM applications support 
confidential information exchange with 
the customer (+) 
The use of EM supports transparent 
service delivery to customers (+) 
Personal trust Replace offline with 
online interaction (–) 
Replace offline with online 
interaction (–) 
Replace offline with online interaction 
(–) 
EM, electronic market.
Business relationships in electronic markets 
© 2005 Blackwell Publishing Ltd, Information Systems Journal 15, 321–341 
331 
The descriptive data displays were followed by explanatory data displays, which served 
to identify relationships among the different variables, and eventually led to conclusion 
drawing and verification. The explanatory data display used was causal networks. Causal 
network are techniques that map the relationships (arrows) between variables (nodes) in 
the study, where such relationships imply causality rather than just correlation (Miles & 
Huberman, 1994). Casual networks served to explain the relations between the emerging 
codes. 
Following Miles and Huberman’s recommendations (1994), ‘noting patterns’, and 
based on these patterns, ‘identifying relations between variables’ were the first steps 
in building causal networks. For example, during the first case, the use of EM was 
frequently associated with relationships involving high transaction costs. According to 
the interviewees, the same pattern appeared: to develop and then use EM to medi-ate 
the transactions with other parties required high set up costs. In order for the 
organization to accept such costs, high costs savings had to be achieved through the 
use of EM in those transactions. Because the use of EM was seen as reducing 
the costs of information sharing between organization, such costs saving would be 
higher where there is a high level of interaction going on between the organization, 
i.e. high transaction costs. Such pattern emerging through the data supported the 
drawing of the first tentative links in the causal networks. In situations in which the 
relations between two variables could not be precisely explained, for example between 
the use of EM and the duration of business relationships, ‘finding the intervening vari-ables’, 
that is the switching costs associated with EM use which explain why the par-ties 
prolong the relationship, was a useful tactic to develop the links in the network. 
As causal networks were constantly refined, tentative conclusions could be developed 
for each case. 
The tactic used to bring together all the patterns and relations identified across the three 
cases, and to develop the conclusions was ‘building a chain of evidence’, as suggested by 
Miles & Huberman (1994). For example, the choice to use EM and the level of trust between 
the parties appeared to be related in both cases. Figure 3 describes the causal network built 
to explain this relation. 
The logical chain was constructed gradually as the analysis progressed and the causal net-works 
were successively compared against the new evidence and refined as a result. At each 
step in the cases’ analysis, the links were verified as following interviewees were asked to 
check them. Such constant verification and refining were facilitated by the flexible approach to 
data collection which allowed new questions to be added and new topics to be explored during 
the interviews. 
Following Miles & Huberman (1994), casual networks narratives were developed to 
verify that the interpretation obtained from the casual network is plausible. The narra-tives 
helped to identify and explain the context, to describe the casual relationships 
mapped onto the network, and to explain why the variables are chained as they are. 
These narratives led to the development of the case outputs that are described in the 
next section.
R Bunduchi 
Figure 3. Electronic markets 
(EM) use and trust. 
Open communication 
between the parties 
(such as through 
discussion forums) 
• The existence of trust positively 
Sharing confidential 
information (such 
product information) 
Explanation 
influences the use of EM 
between organisations as it 
reduces the risks that the other 
party will behave 
opportunistically and take 
advantage of the information 
exchanged. At the same time, if 
EM is used to share confidential 
information, and to support open 
communication, then it creates 
confidence in the other party 
thus facilitating trust building. In 
this way, the directions of 
influence among variables, i.e. 
trust and EM use, were identified 
and explained. 
Characteristics OrgA OrgB 
Role Supplier of consultancy services for the 
Supplier of energy services for business 
and home customers 
Ownership OrgA OrgB 
Functionalities Information services such as industry news and white 
papers, event calendar, generic discussion forums, 
newsletters 
Information services such as industry news 
and white papers 
Catalogue and consulting services and dedicated 
message services, shared databases 
Electronic billing, internet invoicing, 
data visualization and analysis tools, 
data forecasting 
Time in use 5 years 2 years 
© 2005 Blackwell Publishing Ltd, Information Systems Journal 15, 321–341 
332 
EM use 
EM 
USAGE 
- 
Fear that the other 
party will take 
advantage of the 
information exchanged 
through the EM 
TRUST 
BUILDING 
Table 4. Electronic market’s characteristics 
petroleum industry 
4. CASE STUDIES 
as a dvance 
The characteristics of EM applications and the type of relationships included in the study are 
described in Table 4. 
The use of EM and their outcomes on the nature of customer relationships is explained in the 
following sections. 
4.1. OrgA 
OrgA is a service company part of one of the leading groups in the petroleum industry. OrgA 
offers technical consultancy services ranging from providing the technology for extraction and 
exploration to developing the software for oil trading operations. Although the company was
Business relationships in electronic markets 
© 2005 Blackwell Publishing Ltd, Information Systems Journal 15, 321–341 
333 
created in order to expand the parent company’s research and technical consultancy market, 
the majority of OrgA’s customers are the parent group’s operating companies. 
OrgA differentiates between their customers based on their belonging to the parent group 
(internal vs. external customers), and the duration and financial value of their contract. In gen-eral, 
internal customers are ‘high value companies’ with whom OrgA ‘has the biggest con-tracts’, 
and who are ‘highly profitable’. Such customers are labelled as ‘large customers’ with 
contract running a number of years, in contrast with the ‘small customers’ which are in general 
external customers, with a smaller financial contract, generally running out within one year. 
Although smaller in the financial value of their contract, external customers play a central role 
for OrgA because they allow the company to leverage the various products of parent group’s 
operating companies across a larger market, and thus reduce the costs and increase the effi-ciencies 
in their operations. According to the interviewees, to attract smaller customers was 
one of the strategic drivers that led to the creation of OrgA: 
[OrgA] was created in order to reduce the cost overheads by offering the opportunity to sell 
the technical skills provided by the company’s different business groups to a larger market. 
. . . from the products that the business groups have developed for large customers, we can 
take individual components that can be sold to smaller customers. In this way we can 
increase the market without increasing the costs. (SA) 
Part of the initiative to increase efficiencies while improving customer relationships was the 
development of an EM to support the delivery of consultancy services to internal and external 
customers alike. The services are delivered by selling to the customers a number of licences 
that are rights to access a particular service over the EM. There are three types of licences 
depending on the type of EM functionality provided to customers, as illustrated Table 5. 
Table 5. Services delivered over EM 
Type of licence Target customer Services offered 
Bronze licences Small customers Generic content functionality tailored to the generic requirements of a particular 
market sector. Services include: access to a generic library, newsletters, open and 
generic discussion forums, OrgA promotional information and a generic list of 
contacts within OrgA. 
Silver licences Small customers Similar content functionality as for the bronze licence, but which is customized to 
the requirements of individual customers. Such customized services include 
access to the customers’ own customized libraries, to their own list of OrgA 
contacts; and access to and OrgA expert which can provide confidential advice 
through messaging services. 
Gold licences Large customers In addition of the customized information services, at this level the EM provides 
collaborative functionality tailored to the specific needs of individual customers. 
The information from the customers’ databases is stored within online 
applications, which means that OrgA is able to review most of the data remotely, 
and deliver the service to such customers online through the EM 
EM, electronic market.
R Bunduchi 
© 2005 Blackwell Publishing Ltd, Information Systems Journal 15, 321–341 
334 
Bronze licences are usually acquired by small customers whose contract with OrgA has 
ended, but who are still interested in the information services provided by OrgA. 
According to the interviewees, the major benefit of using the EM application is that it 
improves the coordination of customer relationships. Through providing online functionalities 
such as remote consultancy services, message services and shared databases, the EM 
speeds up the exchange process and decreases communication costs. Faster and cheaper 
communication and coordination leads to lower transaction costs. For example, the use of 
shared databases means that most of the consultancy work is conducted remotely. Remote 
work speeds up the delivery of customer services, and reduces communication and coordi-nation 
costs, as described in the following example: 
for a consultant to review all the data from a plant it took 5 days. Besides, the need to 
have the consultant on the site represents a big overhead for us, and being able to do 
this process remotely means reducing this costs overhead not only in terms of reducing 
the travel costs, but also in terms of a more efficient use of time for the consultant. Dur-ing 
this time, the consultant can also work simultaneously for somebody else, while being 
at the customer’s site means that during that 5 days he can work only for that customer. 
(SA) 
Whereas online interaction generally improves coordination, the delivery of functionalities 
such as shared databases and customized discussion forums increases maintenance costs, 
adding to the overall information processing costs. Nevertheless, customization is required in 
order to increase large customers’ switching costs and thus to restrict their choice of potential 
suppliers. According to one interviewee: 
the use of the applications will be embedded in the customer’s process: so even if the com-petitors 
will have the same applications, will be difficult for the clients to switch the applica-tion. 
The gold licences will allows us to own representation of the customer data [so it] will be 
difficult for the client to switch to another competitor. (SA) 
Higher switching costs restrict the large customers’ choice of potential suppliers. As OrgA 
‘own representation of the customer data’, it finds itself in a better bargaining position in fol-lowing 
negotiations, which translates in lower opportunistic risk for OrgA. However, whereas 
opportunistic risks are lower for OrgB, they become higher for customers because of the 
restrictions in the number of potential suppliers. Additionally, collaborative functionalities such 
as shared databases enable OrgA to gain tight control over the information flows with the cus-tomer, 
hence reducing the operation risks associated with a misrepresentation or withholding 
of information. 
The reduction of communication and coordination costs is done at the expense of personal 
trust. Remote work through online consulting services, e.g. reduces the amount of face-to-face 
communication, hence social exchanges between OrgA and its customers. The interviewees 
emphasized this outcomes as a significant concern for OrgA, because the lack of personal 
contact with customers hinders the development of personal trust that has negative outcomes 
for quality of the overall customer relationship. Nevertheless, the interviewees stated that the
Business relationships in electronic markets 
© 2005 Blackwell Publishing Ltd, Information Systems Journal 15, 321–341 
335 
customers accept the reduction in personal contact because the EM use increases their oper-ation 
efficiency as well. As described by one of the interviewees: 
The disadvantage of the [EM] is that the customers perceive that there will be less face-to-face 
contact [and] the customers will get less personal contact […] but in any case they usu-ally 
phoned the operating companies representatives, which routed them to the expert who 
usually answered the customers’ inquiries later in the week when he had time. On the Cus-tomer 
Web, the access is 24 h per day, so it is a much more efficient tool at directing ques-tions. 
(CW) 
Although reducing personal trust, the use of EM enables OrgA to support organizational 
trust development. First, by using customized content functionalties, OrgA uses EM to 
exchange confidential information with the customers, hence building customers’ confidence in 
the organization. Second, organizational trust development is facilitated by using the content 
functionalities of EM such as discussion forum which enable transparent service delivery. 
According to the interviewees: 
each service failure will contribute to decrease the customers’ trust in the channel, so in 
order to increase [customers] trust we need to make sure that the channel is a transparent 
as possible. The transparency is sustained by the existence of discussion forums. (CW) 
Discussion forums enable customers to communicate between themselves and with OrgA 
thus increasing the transparency in the relationship and building customers’ confidence in 
OrgA’s good faith, which can compensate for the negative outcome of a service failure. This is 
an illustration of risk-based trust: any service failure undermines the risk-based trust, i.e. the 
confidence in the ability of the partner to comply with its promises. However, goodwill trust 
based on confidence that the partner acts in good faith, even if he errs, can compensate for a 
decrease in the risk-based trust. In conclusion, EM has a range of outcomes on transaction 
costs and goodwill trust: in reduces personal trust but it increases organizational trust, reduces 
transaction cost while at the same time increasing them to enable opportunism risks reduc-tions, 
and finally reduces operation risks. 
4.2. OrgB 
OrgB is a integrated multi-utility company, including gas as well as electricity businesses 
(although the former is significantly lower in terms of revenue than the latter), and participating 
in all four activities in the energy supply chain: generation, transmission, distribution and sup-ply. 
This study focuses on the electricity group, and the use of EM in their customers relation-ships. 
For the purpose of this study, customers are defined here as the end customers, i.e. the 
consumers of electricity such as plants, hotels and households. 
OrgB classifies its customers based on the financial value of their contract, i.e. their energy 
consumption. Residential customers include home and small businesses customers with an 
energy consumption less then 1 MW per year. Large business includes customers with an 
energy consumption higher than 1 MW per year.
R Bunduchi 
© 2005 Blackwell Publishing Ltd, Information Systems Journal 15, 321–341 
336 
In an effort to achieve cost savings, OrgB set up the EM to support payment and deliver elec-tricity 
services with both residential and large business customers. The services delivered over 
EM depend on the type of customer, as illustrated in Table 6. 
OrgB emphasizes cost savings as the principal outcome of using the EM with both residen-tial 
and large business customers. As one respondent mentioned: 
At the end of the day, the whole scope of the technology is to reduce costs, either by reduc-ing 
personal contact, which unfortunately means less people, or by allowing the company to 
move quickly, and achieve more flexibility. (GM) 
Cost reductions are achieve through functionalities such as electronic billing and internet 
invoicing services which significantly reduce paper- and phone-based communication costs, 
while at the same time reducing the number of personnel dealing with customers. These reduc-tions 
are illustrated by the following response: 
the [EM] produces cost savings: it reduces the cost to serve the customer. For the online cus-tomers, 
we don’t send any paper bill anymore, all the correspondence is done online. So 
there are the cost savings for the paper billing. . . . All the benefits come from the cost sav-ings, 
not only paper, but also the reduction in the personnel that deals with the customers. 
There is no need for so many people anymore to answer the phone, or look for information, 
as everything is handled online. (PM) 
Electronic market commercial functionalities such as electronic billing and internet invoicing 
enhance the transparency of service delivery enabling online customers to check the level of 
their energy consumption whenever they want. They can also pay the bill online whenever they 
choose during a quarter, rather than having to wait for OrgB to issue the bill at the end of the 
quarter. This reduces customers’ misunderstandings regarding the amount of energy con-sumption, 
which according to the interviewees is commonplace when the customer receives a 
paper-based bill. As these misunderstandings represent that largest part of all communication 
Table 6. Electronic market functionalities in OrgB 
Type of customer Services offered 
Residential customer Offers primarily commerce functionality in the form of online billing which allows the customer to 
create and pay the bill online. 
It provides limited information services such as contact information. 
Large business Internet invoicing which enables customers to analyse the invoices online or download the 
information directly into internal systems. 
Peak demand forecast which provides customers with predicted demand forecasts during the 
winter months (November – February). This enables the customers to identify periods of 
expected high demand and potentially high charges. 
Data services which provides information visualization, analysis and standardized report tools 
to the customers. 
Content functionalities such as demos, contact information, industry news and papers.
Business relationships in electronic markets 
© 2005 Blackwell Publishing Ltd, Information Systems Journal 15, 321–341 
337 
between customers and OrgB, the use of EM means not only cheaper communication 
(because online communication is cheaper than paper- and phone-based communication), but 
also less communication between OrgB and its customers that further reduces the communi-cation, 
and improves coordination. As described by one respondent: 
[online customers] can create the bill whenever they want. They don’t have to wait 90 days, 
which is the time it takes us to send out the bill to paper-based customers. The [energy] con-sumption 
is much more visible for them online. Online customers can also phone or send us 
an e-mail if they have any questions . . . [there is] less communication than with offline cus-tomers. 
The type of messages that we have with online customers is if something is not 
working, or if they want to change something, but the rest of the problems are avoided with 
online customers. (PM) 
In contrast with OrgA, no evidence was found in this case of an increase in the level of trans-action 
costs as a result of EM use. One explanation may be the limited experience with the 
deployment of EM, as EM was launched by OrgB only 2 years ago. 
As mentioned by one respondent, whereas commerce functionalities such as electronic bill-ing 
enable less and cheaper communication with the customer, and ease the coordination of 
the overall relationship, it also reduces personal contact that inhibits personal trust develop-ment. 
Personal trust requires social exchanges between the parties involved in a relationship, 
and such exchanges are more likely to happen over the phone and face-to-face than through 
online communication (email). As the respondents argued: 
E-mail doesn’t let you build a personal relationship, or develop trust in the person you com-municate 
with. (RMTM) 
Whereas in the case of residential customers such social exchanges were already limited 
(because only phone- and paper-based channels were open to them), the decline in social 
exchanges is higher for large businesses customers who were dealt directly and personally by 
an OrgB representative. 
None of the functionalities provided through the EM support (or inhibit) organizational trust 
building. No evidence was found to suggest that OrgB is concerned with or attempts to support 
goodwill trust through the use of EM. At the same time, the respondents did not perceived any 
changes in the level of transaction risks as a result of EM use with the customers. 
4.3. Discussion 
The two case studies analyse two different models of EM use in interorganizational relation-ships, 
a collaborative model in the first case, and a transactional model in the second case. 
In both models, a major outcome of EM use is transaction costs reductions, sustained 
through commerce functionalities such as remote consultancy services, electronic billing as 
well as collaborative functionalities such as dedicated messaging service. Such an outcome 
supports the large body of TCE-based studies which argue that IT in general, EM in particular 
lowers transaction costs (Malone et al., 1987; Bakos, 1991; Hart & Estrin, 1991).
R Bunduchi 
© 2005 Blackwell Publishing Ltd, Information Systems Journal 15, 321–341 
338 
In the collaborative model, we found that EM use can increase communication and 
information processing costs. The explanation relates to the trade-offs involved in collabo-rative 
EM use. These trade-offs refer to the choices that the organization makes between 
the different outcomes of EM functionalities on its objectives. Whilst the use of content 
and collaborative functionalities such as customized discussion forums and shared data 
bases adds to the level of transaction costs, they also increase customers’ switching costs 
leading to lower opportunism risks. As such transaction risks are higher in collaborative 
relationships (Clemons et al., 1993), the organization places more emphasis on the ability 
of EM to reduce transaction risks, than the ability of EM to reduce transaction costs. Con-sequently, 
the owner of the EM (in our case the supplier) assesses the different out-comes 
that EM functionalities have on its objectives, and selects to use those that best 
achieve its objectives. 
A similar trade-off in the collaborative model relates to transaction costs and personal trust. 
Commerce functionalities such as electronic billing and remote consultancy services are used 
to reduce transaction costs, although they hinder personal trust. The deliberate choice to 
reduce personal trust, although a significant concern for OrgA as it hampers collaboration in 
the relationships suggests that personal trust plays an inferior role to organizational trust in 
supporting the collaborative nature of interorganizational relationships. This support Zaheer 
et al’s (1998) study which found that the influence of personal trust on the nature of a business 
relationship is limited and subordinated to organizational trust. 
Consequently, in collaborative relationships, the use of EM is marked by trade-offs between 
different functionalities. Organizations balance their objectives, and assess the outcomes that 
the content, commerce and collaborative EM functionalities have on these objectives. This bal-ancing 
between the different outcomes of EM functionalities on the overall objectives of the 
organizations governs the way organizations use EM applications in their collaborative 
relationships. 
In contrast, in the transaction models, transaction costs reduction is the primary intended 
outcome of EM use. The reduction in personal trust which occurs as a result of commerce func-tionality 
such as electronic billing is acknowledged as a side-effect of EM use, but is not con-sidered 
as a significant outcome. As the relationships are transactional, personal trust is not a 
relevant variable in the exchange (Morgan & Hunt, 1994; Lambe et al., 2001). Therefore, the 
use of transactional EM does not involve trade-offs, as the primary focus is on deploying com-merce 
functionalities to reduce transaction cost. 
The study also finds that as suggested by Clemons et al. (1993), EM use lowers transaction 
risks in the collaborative model. Collaborative functionalities such as shared databases reduce 
operational risks by enabling better control over the information exchanged, whereas the ability 
to customize the EM to increase the partner’s switching costs improves the bargaining position 
of the organization developing the EM and thus reduces opportunism risks. 
Evidence that EM support organizational goodwill trust is also found in the collaborative 
model, through the use of collaborative functionalities such as shared databases, and through 
the use of content functionalities such as discussion forums. The explanation of the later is that 
such information sharing enables the organization to build and maintain a sense community
Business relationships in electronic markets 
© 2005 Blackwell Publishing Ltd, Information Systems Journal 15, 321–341 
339 
within its customer users which enhances trust in the organization that manages such com-munity, 
as suggested by Luo, (2002). In line with previous studies (Hart & Saunders, 1998; Gal-livan 
& Depledge, 2003), in the collaborative model, EM use was found to sustain organization 
trust through increasing the amount of confidential information exchanged between parties and 
through enhancing the transparency of the service. 
5. CONCLUSIONS AND FUTURE RESEARCH 
This article investigated the outcomes that EM use has on collaborative and transactional rela-tionships 
between buyer and seller organizations by addressing the transaction cost and trust 
dimensions together. 
The study is based on a multi-case study research design that has a number of limitations. 
First, the study includes only dyadic relationships between buyers and sellers that are analysed 
only from the perspective of the organization under study. However, the objectives that orga-nizations 
pursue in their interorganizational relationships and the trade-offs that govern the use 
of EM in these relationships might depend on the wider internet-worked context in which orga-nizations 
currently operate (Castells, 2000). Additionally, the perspective of the other party 
regarding the outcomes of EM use and the trade-offs that they are prepared to accept are not 
taken into account. For this reason, the study provides only a limited view on the EM use in 
interorganizational relationships, and has to be extended by assessing the objectives and the 
trade-offs that both partners have to make in their usage of EM. Secondly, the nature of ser-vices 
transacted over the EM in the two cases is different which might affect the level of trans-action 
costs. Consequently, future research is required to test the wider applicability of the 
findings. Such studies should include a wider range of organizations, should address the net-work 
level of EM use and, most importantly, should include all the partners involved in a par-ticular 
instance of EM use. 
Notwithstanding these limitations, this study bring three significant contributions to the IS 
literature. 
First, a thorough investigation of the role that trust together with transaction costs have for 
the use of EM is lacking from the mainstream literature, although there have been claims that 
these dimensions should be addressed together (Steinfield et al., 1995; Kumar et al., 1998; 
Christiaanse & Kumar, 2000). Relying on two in-depth studies of collaborative and transactional 
uses of EM, this study explains the outcomes of EM use on collaborative and transactional 
buyer–seller relationships by addressing these dimensions together. 
Second, the study found that the collaborative use of EM is shaped by the trade-offs that 
organizations make between the outcomes that different EM functionalities have on their col-laborative 
objectives. Organizations assesses the outcomes that different content, commerce 
and collaboration EM functionalities have on their objectives relating to transaction costs and 
trust, and selects to use those that allow the best way to achieve them. In contrast, such trade-offs 
are not involved in transactional uses of EM, as the main focus here is to achieve trans-action 
cost reductions.
R Bunduchi 
© 2005 Blackwell Publishing Ltd, Information Systems Journal 15, 321–341 
340 
Finally, the study provides empirical support to the assertion that the TCE framework is lim-ited 
in its ability to account for collaborative uses of EM, as suggested in previous research 
(Kumar et al., 1998; Markus & Christiaanse, 2003). 
REFERENCES 
Backhaus, K. & Buschken, J. (1997) What do we know 
about business-to-business interactions? – a synopsis of 
empirical research on buyer–seller interactions. In: Rela-tionships 
and Networks in International Markets, 
Gemunden, H.G., Ritter, T. & Walter, A. (eds), pp. 13– 
33. Elsevier, Pergamon, UK. 
Bakos, Y. (1991) A strategic analysis of electronic market-places. 
MIS Quarterly, 15, 295–310. 
Bakos, Y. (1998) The emerging role of electronic market-places 
on the internet. Communications of the ACM, 41, 
35–42. 
Bakos, Y. & Brynjolfsson, E. (1997) Organizational part-nership 
and the virtual corporation. In: Information Tech-nology 
and Industrial Competitiveness: How Information 
Technology Shapes Competition, Kemerer, C.F. (ed.), 
pp. 1–18. Kluwer, Amsterdam, the Netherlands. 
Castells, M. (2000) The Information Age: Economy, Soci-ety, 
and Culture. Vol. 1: The Rise of the Network Econ-omy. 
Blackwell Publishers, Oxford, UK. 
Christiaanse, E. & Kumar, K. (2000) ICT-enabled coordi-nation 
of dynamic supply webs. International Journal of 
Physical Distribution and Logistics, 30, 268–285. 
Christiaanse, E., van Diepen, T. & Damsgaard, J. (2004) 
Proprietary versus internet technologies and the adop-tion 
and impact of electronic marketplaces. Journal of 
Strategic Information Systems, 13, 151–165. 
Clemons, E.K., Reddi, S.P. & Row, M.C. (1993) The 
impact of information technology on the organization 
of economic activity: the ‘Move to the middle’ hypothe-sis. 
Journal of Management Information Systems, 10, 
9–35. 
Creswell, J.W. (1994) Research Design Qualitative and 
Quantitative Approaches. SAGE, Thousand Oaks, CA, 
USA. 
Dyer, J.H., Cho, D.S. & Chu, W. (1998) Strategic supplier 
segmentation: the next ‘Best Practice’ in supply chain 
management. California Management Review, 40, 57– 
77. 
Easton, G. (1997) Industrial Networks: A review. In: Under-standing 
Business Markets Ford, D. (ed.), pp. 102–128. 
The Dryden Press, London, UK. 
Gallivan, M.J. & Depledge, G. (2003) Trust, control and 
the role of interorganizational systems in electronic 
partnership. Information Systems Journal, 13, 159– 
190. 
Garcia-Dastugue, S.J. & Lambert, D.M. (2003) Internet-enabled 
coordination in the supply chain. Industrial Mar-keting 
Management, 32, 251–263. 
Geun Lee, H. & Clark, T.H. (1996/97) Market process re-eingineering 
through electronic market systems. Oppor-tunities 
and Challenges Journal of Management 
Information Systems, 13, 113–136. 
Gulati, R., Nohria, N. & Zaheer, A. (2000) Strategic net-works. 
Strategic Management Journal, 21, 203–215. 
Hart, P. & Estrin, D. (1991) Inter-organization networks, 
Computer integration, and shifts in interdependence: the 
case of the semiconductor industry. ACM Transactions 
on Information Systems, 9, 370–398. 
Hart, P.J. & Saunders, C.S. (1998) Emerging electronic 
partnerships: antecedents and dimensions of EDI use 
from the supplier’s perspective. Journal of Management 
Information Systems, 14, 87–111. 
Hussey, J. & Hussey, R. (1997) Business Research. Mac- 
Millan Business, London, UK. 
Kraut, R., Steinfield, C., Chan, A., Butler, B. & Hoag, A. 
(1998) Coordination and virtualisation: the role of elec-tronic 
networks and personal relationships. Journal of 
Computer-Mediated Communications, 3, 1–34. 
Kumar, K. & van Dissel, H. (1996) Sustainable collabora-tion: 
managing conflict and cooperation in interorganisa-tional 
systems MIS Quarterly, 20, 279–300. 
Kumar, K., Dissel, H. & Bielli, P. (1998) The merchant of 
Prato – revisited: toward a third rationality of information 
systems. MIS Quarterly, 22, 199–227. 
Lambe, C.J., Wittmann, C.M. & Spekman, R.E. (2001) 
Social exchange theory and research on business-to-business 
relational exchange. Journal of Business to 
Business Marketing, 8, 1–36. 
Leek, S., Turnbull, P.W. & Naude, P. (2003) How is infor-mation 
technology affecting business relationships? 
Results from a UK survey. Industrial Marketing Manage-ment, 
32, 119–126.
Business relationships in electronic markets 
© 2005 Blackwell Publishing Ltd, Information Systems Journal 15, 321–341 
341 
Luo, X. (2002) Trust production and privacy concerns on 
the Internet. A framework based on relationship market-ing 
and social exchange theory. Industrial Marketing 
Management, 31, 111–118. 
Malone, T.W., Yates, J. & Benjamin, R.I. (1987) Electronic 
markets and electronic hierarchies. Communications of 
the ACM, 30, 484–497. 
Markus, M.L. & Christiaanse, E. (2003) Adoption and 
impact of collaboration electronic marketplaces. Informa-tion 
Systems and E-Business Management, 1, 139–155. 
Meier, J. (1995) The importance of relationship manage-ment 
in establishing successful interorganisational 
systems. Journal of Strategic Information Systems, 4, 
135–148. 
Miles, M.B. & Huberman, A.M. (1994) Qualitative Data 
Analyisis: an Expanded Sourcebook. Sage Publications, 
Thousand Oaks, CA, USA. 
Morgan, R.M. & Hunt, S.D. (1994) The commitment-trust 
theory of relationships marketing. Journal of Marketing, 
58, 20–38. 
Ngwenyama, O.K. & Lee, A.S. (1997) Communication rich-ness 
in electronic mail: critical social theory and the con-textuality 
of meaning. MIS Quarterly, 21, 145–167. 
Nooteboom, B. (1996) Trust, opportunism and gover-nance: 
a process and control model. Organization Stud-ies, 
17, 985–1010. 
Pavlou, P.A. (2002) Institution-based trust in interorgani-zational 
exchange relationships: the role of online B2B 
marketplaces on trust formation. Journal of Strategic 
Information Systems, 11, 215–243. 
Ratnasingam, P. (2005) Trust in inter-organizational 
exchanges: a case study in business to business elec-tronic 
commerce. Decision Support Systems, 39, 524– 
544. 
Remenyi, D., Williams, B., Money, A. & Swartz, E. (2000) 
Doing Research in Business and Management. Sage 
Publications, London, UK. 
Russell, S. & Williams, R. (2002) Social shaping of tech-nology: 
frameworks, findings and implications for policy 
with glossary of social shaping concepts. In: Shaping 
Technology, Guiding Policy, Sorensen, K.H. & Williams, 
R. (eds), pp. 37–132. Edward Elgar, Chetlenham, UK. 
Sako, M. (1992) Prices, Quality and Trust: Inter-Firm Rela-tions 
in Britain and Japan. Cambridge University Press, 
Cambridge, UK. 
Smith Ring, P. & Van de Ven, A.H. (1992) Structuring 
cooperative relationships between organisations. Strate-gic 
Management Journal, 13, 483–498. 
Smith Ring, P. & Van de Ven, A.H. (1994) Developmental 
processes of cooperative interorganizational relation-ships. 
Academy of Management Review, 19, 90–118. 
Soliman, K.S. & Janz, B.D. (2004) An exploratory study to 
identify the critical factors affecting the decision to estab-lish 
Internet-based interorganizational information sys-tems. 
Information and Management, 41, 696–706. 
Srinivasan, S. (2004) Role of trust in e-business success. 
Information Management and Computer Security, 12, 
66–72. 
Stake, R.E. (1995) The Art of Case Study Research. Sage 
Publications, Thousand Oaks, CA, USA. 
Steinfield, C., Kraut, R. & Plummer, A. (1995) The impact 
of interorganizational networks on buyer–seller relation-ships. 
Journal of Computer-Mediated Communications, 
1, 1–17. 
Strauss, A. & Corbin, J. (1990) Basics of Qualitative 
Research Grounded Theory Procedures and Tech-niques. 
Sage Publications, Thousand Oaks, CA, USA. 
Vlosky, R.P., Fontenot, R. & Blalock, L. (2000) Extranets: 
impacts on business practices and relationships. Journal 
of Business and Industrial Marketing, 15, 438–457. 
Williamson, O.E. (1986) Economic Organization Firms, 
Markets and Policy Control. New York University Press, 
New York, USA. 
Williamson, O.E. (1993) Calculativeness, trust, and eco-nomic 
organisation. Journal of Law and Economics, 36, 
453–486. 
Yin, R.K. (1994) Case Study Research Design and Meth-ods. 
Sage Publication, Thousand Oaks, CA, USA. 
Zaheer, A., McEvily, B. & Perrone, V. (1998) Does trust 
matter? Exploring the effects of interorganizational and 
interpersonal trust on performance. Organization Sci-ence, 
9, 141–159. 
Biography 
Raluca Bunduchi is a lecturer in Management at the Busi-ness 
School, Aberdeen University. Prior to this, she worked 
as a Research Fellow in the Research Centre for Social 
Sciences at the University of Edinburgh. She studied for 
her PhD in the Department of Management Science at 
Strathclyde Business School in Glasgow examining the 
use of internet technologies and their implications for the 
nature of business relationships within and across organi-zational 
boundaries. Raluca Bunduchi can be reached at 
bunduchi@yahoo.com
Ps26

More Related Content

What's hot

FAIRNESS: A CHALLENGE FOR THE DISTRIBUTION OF COOPERATION GAINS IN VALUE CHAINS
FAIRNESS: A CHALLENGE FOR THE DISTRIBUTION OF COOPERATION GAINS IN VALUE CHAINSFAIRNESS: A CHALLENGE FOR THE DISTRIBUTION OF COOPERATION GAINS IN VALUE CHAINS
FAIRNESS: A CHALLENGE FOR THE DISTRIBUTION OF COOPERATION GAINS IN VALUE CHAINSijmvsc
 
Critical evaluation of the potential of stakeholder theory to contribute to u...
Critical evaluation of the potential of stakeholder theory to contribute to u...Critical evaluation of the potential of stakeholder theory to contribute to u...
Critical evaluation of the potential of stakeholder theory to contribute to u...Kennedy Mbwette
 
How quality, value, image, and satisfaction create loyalty at an iran telecom
How quality, value, image, and satisfaction create loyalty at an iran telecomHow quality, value, image, and satisfaction create loyalty at an iran telecom
How quality, value, image, and satisfaction create loyalty at an iran telecomCuong Dinh
 
Complex Contracting in the Public Sector
Complex Contracting in the Public SectorComplex Contracting in the Public Sector
Complex Contracting in the Public SectorJon Hansen
 
Perceived organizational justice and employees’ organizational citizenship be...
Perceived organizational justice and employees’ organizational citizenship be...Perceived organizational justice and employees’ organizational citizenship be...
Perceived organizational justice and employees’ organizational citizenship be...Alexander Decker
 
INTEGRATED FRAMEWORK TO MODEL DATA WITH BUSINESS PROCESS AND BUSINESS RULES
INTEGRATED FRAMEWORK TO MODEL DATA WITH BUSINESS PROCESS AND BUSINESS RULESINTEGRATED FRAMEWORK TO MODEL DATA WITH BUSINESS PROCESS AND BUSINESS RULES
INTEGRATED FRAMEWORK TO MODEL DATA WITH BUSINESS PROCESS AND BUSINESS RULESijdms
 
Adversarial and cooperative models in contracting for public services
Adversarial and cooperative models in contracting for public servicesAdversarial and cooperative models in contracting for public services
Adversarial and cooperative models in contracting for public servicesShantanu Basu
 
Yes Virginia! A Profile In Excellence White Paper
Yes Virginia! A Profile In Excellence White PaperYes Virginia! A Profile In Excellence White Paper
Yes Virginia! A Profile In Excellence White PaperJon Hansen
 
Collaboration in Buyer-Seller Relationships as a New Approach to Competitive ...
Collaboration in Buyer-Seller Relationships as a New Approach to Competitive ...Collaboration in Buyer-Seller Relationships as a New Approach to Competitive ...
Collaboration in Buyer-Seller Relationships as a New Approach to Competitive ...IOSR Journals
 
Outsourcing
OutsourcingOutsourcing
OutsourcingJan Zika
 
Corporate social disclosure quantity and quality as moderators between corpor...
Corporate social disclosure quantity and quality as moderators between corpor...Corporate social disclosure quantity and quality as moderators between corpor...
Corporate social disclosure quantity and quality as moderators between corpor...Alexander Decker
 
Merkl-Davies, Doris M. and Brennan, Niamh M. [2007] Discretionary Disclosure ...
Merkl-Davies, Doris M. and Brennan, Niamh M. [2007] Discretionary Disclosure ...Merkl-Davies, Doris M. and Brennan, Niamh M. [2007] Discretionary Disclosure ...
Merkl-Davies, Doris M. and Brennan, Niamh M. [2007] Discretionary Disclosure ...Prof Niamh M. Brennan
 
Customer relationship management_in_call_centers
Customer relationship management_in_call_centersCustomer relationship management_in_call_centers
Customer relationship management_in_call_centersVarun Pandey
 
Jakari griffiththe influence of cross race interpersonal efficacy-2007
Jakari griffiththe influence of cross race interpersonal efficacy-2007Jakari griffiththe influence of cross race interpersonal efficacy-2007
Jakari griffiththe influence of cross race interpersonal efficacy-2007Dr. Jakari Griffith
 
Price fairness and its linear dependence on consumer attitude
Price fairness and its linear dependence on consumer attitudePrice fairness and its linear dependence on consumer attitude
Price fairness and its linear dependence on consumer attitudeAlexander Decker
 

What's hot (20)

FAIRNESS: A CHALLENGE FOR THE DISTRIBUTION OF COOPERATION GAINS IN VALUE CHAINS
FAIRNESS: A CHALLENGE FOR THE DISTRIBUTION OF COOPERATION GAINS IN VALUE CHAINSFAIRNESS: A CHALLENGE FOR THE DISTRIBUTION OF COOPERATION GAINS IN VALUE CHAINS
FAIRNESS: A CHALLENGE FOR THE DISTRIBUTION OF COOPERATION GAINS IN VALUE CHAINS
 
Critical evaluation of the potential of stakeholder theory to contribute to u...
Critical evaluation of the potential of stakeholder theory to contribute to u...Critical evaluation of the potential of stakeholder theory to contribute to u...
Critical evaluation of the potential of stakeholder theory to contribute to u...
 
How quality, value, image, and satisfaction create loyalty at an iran telecom
How quality, value, image, and satisfaction create loyalty at an iran telecomHow quality, value, image, and satisfaction create loyalty at an iran telecom
How quality, value, image, and satisfaction create loyalty at an iran telecom
 
Complex Contracting in the Public Sector
Complex Contracting in the Public SectorComplex Contracting in the Public Sector
Complex Contracting in the Public Sector
 
Perceived organizational justice and employees’ organizational citizenship be...
Perceived organizational justice and employees’ organizational citizenship be...Perceived organizational justice and employees’ organizational citizenship be...
Perceived organizational justice and employees’ organizational citizenship be...
 
INTEGRATED FRAMEWORK TO MODEL DATA WITH BUSINESS PROCESS AND BUSINESS RULES
INTEGRATED FRAMEWORK TO MODEL DATA WITH BUSINESS PROCESS AND BUSINESS RULESINTEGRATED FRAMEWORK TO MODEL DATA WITH BUSINESS PROCESS AND BUSINESS RULES
INTEGRATED FRAMEWORK TO MODEL DATA WITH BUSINESS PROCESS AND BUSINESS RULES
 
Adversarial and cooperative models in contracting for public services
Adversarial and cooperative models in contracting for public servicesAdversarial and cooperative models in contracting for public services
Adversarial and cooperative models in contracting for public services
 
Yes Virginia! A Profile In Excellence White Paper
Yes Virginia! A Profile In Excellence White PaperYes Virginia! A Profile In Excellence White Paper
Yes Virginia! A Profile In Excellence White Paper
 
Banking and Money Essay
Banking and Money EssayBanking and Money Essay
Banking and Money Essay
 
Collaboration in Buyer-Seller Relationships as a New Approach to Competitive ...
Collaboration in Buyer-Seller Relationships as a New Approach to Competitive ...Collaboration in Buyer-Seller Relationships as a New Approach to Competitive ...
Collaboration in Buyer-Seller Relationships as a New Approach to Competitive ...
 
Outsourcing
OutsourcingOutsourcing
Outsourcing
 
Corporate social disclosure quantity and quality as moderators between corpor...
Corporate social disclosure quantity and quality as moderators between corpor...Corporate social disclosure quantity and quality as moderators between corpor...
Corporate social disclosure quantity and quality as moderators between corpor...
 
Merkl-Davies, Doris M. and Brennan, Niamh M. [2007] Discretionary Disclosure ...
Merkl-Davies, Doris M. and Brennan, Niamh M. [2007] Discretionary Disclosure ...Merkl-Davies, Doris M. and Brennan, Niamh M. [2007] Discretionary Disclosure ...
Merkl-Davies, Doris M. and Brennan, Niamh M. [2007] Discretionary Disclosure ...
 
Customer relationship management_in_call_centers
Customer relationship management_in_call_centersCustomer relationship management_in_call_centers
Customer relationship management_in_call_centers
 
Bureaucratic Discretion
Bureaucratic DiscretionBureaucratic Discretion
Bureaucratic Discretion
 
Jakari griffiththe influence of cross race interpersonal efficacy-2007
Jakari griffiththe influence of cross race interpersonal efficacy-2007Jakari griffiththe influence of cross race interpersonal efficacy-2007
Jakari griffiththe influence of cross race interpersonal efficacy-2007
 
Zenios
ZeniosZenios
Zenios
 
Price fairness and its linear dependence on consumer attitude
Price fairness and its linear dependence on consumer attitudePrice fairness and its linear dependence on consumer attitude
Price fairness and its linear dependence on consumer attitude
 
425
425425
425
 
851653
851653851653
851653
 

Viewers also liked (19)

Ps10
Ps10Ps10
Ps10
 
Ps54p
Ps54pPs54p
Ps54p
 
Ps28
Ps28Ps28
Ps28
 
Ps18
Ps18Ps18
Ps18
 
Ps51
Ps51Ps51
Ps51
 
Ps3
Ps3Ps3
Ps3
 
Ps20
Ps20Ps20
Ps20
 
Ps40
Ps40Ps40
Ps40
 
Ps44
Ps44Ps44
Ps44
 
Ps21
Ps21Ps21
Ps21
 
Ps52
Ps52Ps52
Ps52
 
Ps45
Ps45Ps45
Ps45
 
Ps5
Ps5Ps5
Ps5
 
Ps32
Ps32Ps32
Ps32
 
Ps30
Ps30Ps30
Ps30
 
Ps34
Ps34Ps34
Ps34
 
Ps4
Ps4Ps4
Ps4
 
Ps29
Ps29Ps29
Ps29
 
Ps11
Ps11Ps11
Ps11
 

Similar to Ps26

Transaction costs AND INFORMATION EFFICIENCY IN CREDIT INTERMEDIATION
Transaction costs AND INFORMATION EFFICIENCY IN CREDIT INTERMEDIATIONTransaction costs AND INFORMATION EFFICIENCY IN CREDIT INTERMEDIATION
Transaction costs AND INFORMATION EFFICIENCY IN CREDIT INTERMEDIATIONDinabandhu Bag
 
A Conceptual Framework For B2B Electronic Contracting
A Conceptual Framework For B2B Electronic ContractingA Conceptual Framework For B2B Electronic Contracting
A Conceptual Framework For B2B Electronic ContractingLuisa Polanco
 
Determining relevance of “best practice” based on interoperability in Europea...
Determining relevance of “best practice” based on interoperability in Europea...Determining relevance of “best practice” based on interoperability in Europea...
Determining relevance of “best practice” based on interoperability in Europea...ePractice.eu
 
HICSS 50th: Trust in Digital Environments: From the Sharing Economy to Decent...
HICSS 50th: Trust in Digital Environments: From the Sharing Economy to Decent...HICSS 50th: Trust in Digital Environments: From the Sharing Economy to Decent...
HICSS 50th: Trust in Digital Environments: From the Sharing Economy to Decent...Robin Teigland
 
The social dynamics of software development
The social dynamics of software developmentThe social dynamics of software development
The social dynamics of software developmentaliaalistartup
 
Telecommunications law indicators for comparative - Marcio Iorio (2011)
Telecommunications law indicators for comparative - Marcio Iorio (2011)Telecommunications law indicators for comparative - Marcio Iorio (2011)
Telecommunications law indicators for comparative - Marcio Iorio (2011)ACORN-REDECOM
 
A new model for building online trust in b2 c
A new model for building online trust in b2 cA new model for building online trust in b2 c
A new model for building online trust in b2 cAlexander Decker
 
IPSERA 2016. Final paper by A. Okulov, A. van Weele
IPSERA 2016. Final paper by A. Okulov, A. van WeeleIPSERA 2016. Final paper by A. Okulov, A. van Weele
IPSERA 2016. Final paper by A. Okulov, A. van WeeleAnatoly Okulov
 
Value creation in relationship exchange explication by Ethical Approach: an a...
Value creation in relationship exchange explication by Ethical Approach: an a...Value creation in relationship exchange explication by Ethical Approach: an a...
Value creation in relationship exchange explication by Ethical Approach: an a...IOSR Journals
 
Knowledge transfer mechanisms in service business acquisitions
Knowledge transfer mechanisms in service business acquisitionsKnowledge transfer mechanisms in service business acquisitions
Knowledge transfer mechanisms in service business acquisitionsMiia Kosonen
 
Two-sided Internet platforms: A business model lifecycle perspective
Two-sided Internet platforms: A business model lifecycle perspectiveTwo-sided Internet platforms: A business model lifecycle perspective
Two-sided Internet platforms: A business model lifecycle perspectiveLaurent Muzellec
 
MuzellecRonteauLambkin2015
MuzellecRonteauLambkin2015MuzellecRonteauLambkin2015
MuzellecRonteauLambkin2015Laurent Muzellec
 
E commerce buissness-model
E commerce buissness-modelE commerce buissness-model
E commerce buissness-modelPrabhat gangwar
 
Managing collaboration within networks and relationships in the serious game ...
Managing collaboration within networks and relationships in the serious game ...Managing collaboration within networks and relationships in the serious game ...
Managing collaboration within networks and relationships in the serious game ...ijcsit
 
Telecommunications Steering CommitteeManagingTelecommuni.docx
Telecommunications Steering CommitteeManagingTelecommuni.docxTelecommunications Steering CommitteeManagingTelecommuni.docx
Telecommunications Steering CommitteeManagingTelecommuni.docxbradburgess22840
 
Leveraging strategies networks
Leveraging strategies networksLeveraging strategies networks
Leveraging strategies networksJuliet John
 
UNDERSTANDING THE THEORIES AND TYPES OF ENTERPRISE NETWORKS
UNDERSTANDING THE THEORIES AND TYPES OF ENTERPRISE NETWORKSUNDERSTANDING THE THEORIES AND TYPES OF ENTERPRISE NETWORKS
UNDERSTANDING THE THEORIES AND TYPES OF ENTERPRISE NETWORKSNGANG PEREZ
 

Similar to Ps26 (20)

Transaction costs AND INFORMATION EFFICIENCY IN CREDIT INTERMEDIATION
Transaction costs AND INFORMATION EFFICIENCY IN CREDIT INTERMEDIATIONTransaction costs AND INFORMATION EFFICIENCY IN CREDIT INTERMEDIATION
Transaction costs AND INFORMATION EFFICIENCY IN CREDIT INTERMEDIATION
 
A Conceptual Framework For B2B Electronic Contracting
A Conceptual Framework For B2B Electronic ContractingA Conceptual Framework For B2B Electronic Contracting
A Conceptual Framework For B2B Electronic Contracting
 
definingSCM.pdf
definingSCM.pdfdefiningSCM.pdf
definingSCM.pdf
 
Factors Affecting Implementation of E-Procurement Practices in Public Service...
Factors Affecting Implementation of E-Procurement Practices in Public Service...Factors Affecting Implementation of E-Procurement Practices in Public Service...
Factors Affecting Implementation of E-Procurement Practices in Public Service...
 
Determining relevance of “best practice” based on interoperability in Europea...
Determining relevance of “best practice” based on interoperability in Europea...Determining relevance of “best practice” based on interoperability in Europea...
Determining relevance of “best practice” based on interoperability in Europea...
 
HICSS 50th: Trust in Digital Environments: From the Sharing Economy to Decent...
HICSS 50th: Trust in Digital Environments: From the Sharing Economy to Decent...HICSS 50th: Trust in Digital Environments: From the Sharing Economy to Decent...
HICSS 50th: Trust in Digital Environments: From the Sharing Economy to Decent...
 
The social dynamics of software development
The social dynamics of software developmentThe social dynamics of software development
The social dynamics of software development
 
Telecommunications law indicators for comparative - Marcio Iorio (2011)
Telecommunications law indicators for comparative - Marcio Iorio (2011)Telecommunications law indicators for comparative - Marcio Iorio (2011)
Telecommunications law indicators for comparative - Marcio Iorio (2011)
 
A new model for building online trust in b2 c
A new model for building online trust in b2 cA new model for building online trust in b2 c
A new model for building online trust in b2 c
 
IPSERA 2016. Final paper by A. Okulov, A. van Weele
IPSERA 2016. Final paper by A. Okulov, A. van WeeleIPSERA 2016. Final paper by A. Okulov, A. van Weele
IPSERA 2016. Final paper by A. Okulov, A. van Weele
 
Crowdfunding
CrowdfundingCrowdfunding
Crowdfunding
 
Value creation in relationship exchange explication by Ethical Approach: an a...
Value creation in relationship exchange explication by Ethical Approach: an a...Value creation in relationship exchange explication by Ethical Approach: an a...
Value creation in relationship exchange explication by Ethical Approach: an a...
 
Knowledge transfer mechanisms in service business acquisitions
Knowledge transfer mechanisms in service business acquisitionsKnowledge transfer mechanisms in service business acquisitions
Knowledge transfer mechanisms in service business acquisitions
 
Two-sided Internet platforms: A business model lifecycle perspective
Two-sided Internet platforms: A business model lifecycle perspectiveTwo-sided Internet platforms: A business model lifecycle perspective
Two-sided Internet platforms: A business model lifecycle perspective
 
MuzellecRonteauLambkin2015
MuzellecRonteauLambkin2015MuzellecRonteauLambkin2015
MuzellecRonteauLambkin2015
 
E commerce buissness-model
E commerce buissness-modelE commerce buissness-model
E commerce buissness-model
 
Managing collaboration within networks and relationships in the serious game ...
Managing collaboration within networks and relationships in the serious game ...Managing collaboration within networks and relationships in the serious game ...
Managing collaboration within networks and relationships in the serious game ...
 
Telecommunications Steering CommitteeManagingTelecommuni.docx
Telecommunications Steering CommitteeManagingTelecommuni.docxTelecommunications Steering CommitteeManagingTelecommuni.docx
Telecommunications Steering CommitteeManagingTelecommuni.docx
 
Leveraging strategies networks
Leveraging strategies networksLeveraging strategies networks
Leveraging strategies networks
 
UNDERSTANDING THE THEORIES AND TYPES OF ENTERPRISE NETWORKS
UNDERSTANDING THE THEORIES AND TYPES OF ENTERPRISE NETWORKSUNDERSTANDING THE THEORIES AND TYPES OF ENTERPRISE NETWORKS
UNDERSTANDING THE THEORIES AND TYPES OF ENTERPRISE NETWORKS
 

More from Can Erdem (16)

Ps55
Ps55Ps55
Ps55
 
Ps53
Ps53Ps53
Ps53
 
Ps50
Ps50Ps50
Ps50
 
Ps49
Ps49Ps49
Ps49
 
Ps48p
Ps48pPs48p
Ps48p
 
Ps47
Ps47Ps47
Ps47
 
Ps46p
Ps46pPs46p
Ps46p
 
Ps43p
Ps43pPs43p
Ps43p
 
Ps42
Ps42Ps42
Ps42
 
Ps39p
Ps39pPs39p
Ps39p
 
Ps38
Ps38Ps38
Ps38
 
Ps37
Ps37Ps37
Ps37
 
Ps36
Ps36Ps36
Ps36
 
Ps35
Ps35Ps35
Ps35
 
Ps33
Ps33Ps33
Ps33
 
Ps31p
Ps31pPs31p
Ps31p
 

Ps26

  • 1. Info Systems J (2005) 15 , 321–341 © 2005 Blackwell Publishing Ltd 321 Blackwell Science, LtdOxford, UKISJInformation Systems Journal1350-1917Blackwell Publishing Ltd, 200515 321341 Original Article Business relationships in electronic marketsR Bunduchi Business relationships in internet-based electronic markets: the role of goodwill trust and transaction costs Raluca Bunduchi Research Centre for Social Sciences, University of Edinburgh, Edinburgh EH1 1LZ, Scotland, email: bunduchi@yahoo.com Abstract. Transaction costs and goodwill trust, which differentiate between trans-actional and collaborative relationships, were found in existing research to play a significant role in the way organizations use internet technologies to manage their relationships with customers and suppliers within electronic markets (EM). How-ever, a thorough investigation of role that the two dimensions play together in shap-ing the use of EM is lacking from the mainstream literature. This research addresses transaction costs and goodwill trust together to clarify the transforma-tions that internet use has brought on the nature of interorganizational relation-ships that develop between EM players. The research finds the use of EM in collaborative relationships is governed by trade-offs between different outcomes that different EM functionalities have on organizational objectives. Organizations assess these trade-offs, and select those functionalities that best serve to achieve their collaborative relational objectives. In contrast, no trade-offs are find in the transactional model, as the use of EM here is driven principally by transaction cost reductions. Keywords: electronic markets, inter-organizational relationships, transaction cost economics, trust 1 . INTRODUCTION Some of the first researchers to study the consequences that the use of information technology (IT) has on the nature of buyer–seller relationships are Malone, Yates and Benjamin in their seminal article Electronic markets and electronic hierarchies (Malone et al ., 1987). The authors apply the transaction cost economics (TCE) framework and show that IT use lowers transaction costs and favours arms-length relationships between economic actors. Following TCE-based research led to contradictory results regarding the outcome of IT use: Clemons et al .’s (1993) study finds that IT use favours collaborative relationships, whereas Hart and Estrin’s (1991) study suggests that IT use creates incentives for organizations to internalize their activities.
  • 2. R Bunduchi © 2005 Blackwell Publishing Ltd, Information Systems Journal 15 , 321–341 322 A reason for these divergent results is that different types of IT applications can be used to support different types of relationships (Gallivan & Depledge, 2003; Garcia-Dastugue & Lambert, 2003). Organizational research differentiates between two types of buyer–seller rela-tionships: transactional or arms-length relationships, and collaborative or obligational relation-ships. The former are characterized by low interdependence, short-term commitment, prearranged terms and conditions in a written contract, narrow communication channels, low trust and low asset specificity. In contrast, the latter are characterized by strong interde-pendences, high levels of trust and commitment, long-term span, high transaction costs, terms and conditions loosely specified and high asset specificity (Sako, 1992; Morgan & Hunt, 1994; Dyer et al ., 1998; Lambe et al ., 2001). Transactional relationships can be seen as economic exchanges, concerned with the economic exchange of goods and/or services between parties, whereas collaborative relationships involve economic as well as social exchanges such as interdependencies, friendships, closeness and trust (Smith Ring & Van de Ven, 1994; Back-haus & Buschken, 1997; Easton, 1997). As an economic theory, TCE fails to account for social exchanges such as trust and power, which are considered irrelevant to the study of economic exchanges (Williamson, 1993). Therefore, while TCE studies can explain for the outcome of IT use in transactional relationships, they are limited in their ability to account for collaborative outcomes of IT. This study addresses a particular type of internet-enabled application, internet-based elec-tronic markets (EM). This article follows Christiaanse et al . (2004) in defining EM as ‘electronic networks where buyers and sellers meet to engage in buying and selling as well as other activ-ities, such as collaborative planning, logistics, transportation arrangements and fulfilment’ (p. 152). Such a definition acknowledges that EM are not limited to a matter of buying and selling (Bakos, 1991), but may also support a range of other functionalities such as supply chain man-agement solutions, fulfilment and trust mechanisms (Christiaanse et al ., 2004). Depending on their core functionality, Markus & Christiaanse (2003) differentiate between transactional and collaborative EM. Transactional EM provide mainly commerce functional-ities, such as auctions and electronic billing, which enable members to conduct transactions, whereas collaborative EM focus on functionalities which facilitate collaboration, such as shared databases and inventory management. Both types might also provide content func-tionality that does not generate cash flow, but enhance the EM’s core functionality, such as discussions forums and event calendar. The authors argue that transactional EM can be seen as purchasing intermediaries between buyers and sellers and can be analysed within the TCE framework. In contrast, the TCE approach fails to account for the impact of collaborative EM, whose core functionality is processes facilitation, not necessarily the mediation of purchasing transactions. Consequently, the TCE framework alone is inadequate to fully explain for the outcome of EM use on interorganizational relationships (Kumar & Dissel, 1996; Kraut et al ., 1998; Kumar et al ., 1998; Christiaanse & Kumar, 2000; Markus & Christiaanse, 2003). Markus & Christiaanse (2003) suggests that different analytical frameworks are required to address the integration effect of collaborative EM, and the role of power and pre-existing relationships between actors. Kraut et al . (1998) and Kumar et al . (1998) argue that collaboration relational characteristics
  • 3. Business relationships in electronic markets © 2005 Blackwell Publishing Ltd, Information Systems Journal 15 , 321–341 323 such as trust should be included in the TCE analysis to address EM use in collaborative relationships. This article follows the latter recommendations and analyses the collaborative and transac-tional use of IT in relationships between buyers and sellers through addressing transaction cost and goodwill trust. The article is structured as follows: section 2 discusses the theoretical foun-dations of the study and clarifies the transaction costs and trust concepts. The research meth-odology is presented in section 3. Section 4 describes the role that trust and transaction costs play in explaining the nature of business relationships between EM players in two case studies. The research conclusions, limitations and future research are discussed in section 5. 2 . BACKGROUND : TRANSACTION COSTS , TRUST AND EM 2.1. Transaction cost economics-based approaches Research regarding the role of IT in shaping the nature of interorganizational relationships has predominantly adopted a TCE stance. The reason is that TCE explains such relationships in terms of transaction costs, where these transaction costs are directly related to IT use (Malone et al ., 1987). According to TCE, organizations choose between alternative types of business exchanges based on the level of transaction costs (Williamson, 1986). Collaborative exchanges are pre-ferred when transaction costs are high, whereas transactional exchanges are preferred when transaction costs are low (Clemons et al ., 1993). Transaction costs are seen as the crucial vari-able influencing the nature of interorganizational relationships. Transaction cost economics literature differentiates between two categories of transaction costs aspects: 1 Transaction costs – defined as ‘the costs of exchanging information and incorporating that information into decision processes, as well as the costs incurred by the firm due to delays in the communication channel’ (Clemons et al ., 1993, p. 15). 2 Transaction risks – defined as ‘the cost associated with the exposure to being exploited in the relationships’ (Kumar & van Dissel, 1996, p. 292) include operation and opportunism risks. a. Operation risks are ‘the risks that the other parties in the transaction wilfully misrepresent or withhold information, or underperform – that is “skink” – their agreed-upon responsi-bilities’ (Clemons et al ., 1993, p. 15). The existence of high operation risks requires orga-nizations to closely control and monitor the exchange. b. Opportunism risks are ‘the risks associated with a lack of bargaining power or the loss of bargaining power directly resulting from the execution of a relationship, that is, a differ-ence between ex ante and ex post bargaining power’ (Clemons et al ., 1993, p. 16). High asset specificity, few potential partners and loss of resource control as a result of the exchange generate opportunism risks. It is generally assumed in the literature that IT use reduces transaction costs. Malone et al . (1987) argue that IT use reduces the time and cost of communication, decreases the costs of
  • 4. R Bunduchi © 2005 Blackwell Publishing Ltd, Information Systems Journal 15 , 321–341 324 the product selection process, and allows for a tighter coupling of information processes that increases the speed, reduces the errors, and allows for better linkages between the buyers and suppliers’ information systems (IS) which lower transaction costs. This outcome is confirmed in following studies. Bakos (1991; 1998) finds that searching costs are lower within EM, Hart & Estrin (1991) note that IT use improves coordination, while Clemons et al . (1993) argue that IT use reduces the costs of explicit coordination. As according to the TCE framework, lower transaction costs lead to higher reliance on trans-actional exchanges, some researchers argued that EM use facilitates the development of transactional relationships between EM players (Malone et al ., 1987). However, following stud-ies find that IT use enables more efficient control through better information flow, whereas higher reliance on open standards reduces the idiosyncrasy of IT investments which translate in lower operation and opportunism risks (Clemons et al ., 1993). As these risks are higher in collaborative relationships, it means that as EM use reduces transaction risks, organizations have more incentives for collaboration. Following studies confirmed that EM relationships tend to be collaborative in nature (Steinfield et al ., 1995; Bakos & Brynjolfsson, 1997; Christiaanse & Kumar, 2000). Not all empirical research confirms this collaborative effect of IT use. Hart & Estrin (1991) find that EM development is associated with high vulnerability costs such as ‘the costs of adopting specialized procedures, erosion of control over internally generated information’ (p. 376). These vulnerability costs are manifestations of what Clemons et al . (1993) call oppor-tunism risks, i.e. loss of control resulting from specialized investments. Geun Lee & Clark (1996/97) find that EM lead to higher uncertainties as buyers face the risks of incomplete and distorted information, and sellers face the possibility that their offers will not be appropriately valued in an unproved market system. These uncertainties translate in higher opportunism risks, that obstructs EM adoption (Geun Lee & Clark, 1996/97) and encourages internalization of activities (Hart & Estrin, 1991). Figure 1 summarizes these different findings. Different explanations are advanced in the literature to justify for the different outcomes of EM use. They include organizational objectives (Garcia-Dastugue & Lambert, 2003), supply chain characteristics (Christiaanse & Kumar, 2000), and the inability of the TCE framework to account for the integration effects, the history of pre-existing relationships (Markus & Chris-tiaanse, 2003), and the trust and interpersonal relationships between EM players (Steinfield et al ., 1995; Kraut et al ., 1998; Kumar et al ., 1998; Christiaanse & Kumar, 2000). This article focuses on the latter explanation and addresses the role of trust in shaping the use of EM in buyer–seller relationships. 2.2. Beyond economic exchanges: trust and EM Existing research defines trust as a critical characteristic of collaborative interorganizational relationship (Morgan & Hunt, 1994; Zaheer et al ., 1998; Lambe et al ., 2001). However, TCE conceptualizes business relationships in terms of transactions between economic actors, char-acterized by opportunistic behaviour, that is calculative self-interest. In this context, trust is
  • 5. Business relationships in electronic markets Information technologies Figure 1. Transaction costs and risks, and electronic markets (EM). © 2005 Blackwell Publishing Ltd, Information Systems Journal 15 , 321–341 325 ‘warranted when the expected gain from placing oneself at risk is positive, but not otherwise’ (Williamson, 1993, p. 463) and is described as a subclass of risk. Trust based on faith in the other actors is considered irrelevant to the study of economic exchanges. However, trust was found as a critical concept to influence the development of interorganizational relationships in a number of organizational studies (Sako, 1992; Smith Ring & Van de Ven, 1992; 1994; Morgan & Hunt, 1994; Zaheer et al ., 1998) The literature provides two general conceptualizations of trust: risk-based trust, defined as confidence in one’s expectations about another’s behaviour; and goodwill trust, understood as confidence in another’s goodwill (Smith Ring & Van de Ven, 1994; Nooteboom, 1996; Pavlou, 2002). The risk-based perspective on trust acknowledges that parties will employ formal con-tracts to hedge against the uncertainty in the relationship, whereas the goodwill perspective emphasizes the role that interpersonal interactions between organizations play in dealing with this uncertainty. Such interpersonal relationships create faith in the moral integrity of the other party that she will not take advantage of the relationship (Smith Ring & Van de Ven, 1994). This research follows Nooteboom (1996) and Smith Ring & Van de Ven (1992) in addressing the role that goodwill trust has in understanding the nature interorganizational relationships. Goodwill trust can be defined at two levels (Zaheer et al ., 1998): 1 personal level – trust between individuals. 2 organizational level – trust between organizations. Transaction risks Transaction costs Transaction risks Collaborative relationships (Bakos & Brynjolfsson, 1997; Christiaanse & Kumar, 2000; Competitive relationships (Malone et al., 1987) Barriers for EM adoption & internalisation (Hart & Estrin, 1991; Geun Lee & Clark, 1996/97) Efficient control, Better information flow, Open standards Increase communication speed, Reduce communication costs Reduce the costs of searching for and selection of products Increase speed, reduce errors, Improve the linkages between partners informational systems Adoption of specialised procedures, Erosion of control over internally generated information (Hart & Estrin, 1991) Incomplete and distorted information and unproven market systems which increase uncertainties (Geun Lee & Clark, 1996/97) – – + (Clemons et al., 1993) (Clemons et al., 1993; Malone et al., 1987) (Clemons et al., 1993; Malone et al., 1987) (Malone et al., 1987) Clemons et al., 1993) Steinfield et al., 1995)
  • 6. R Bunduchi © 2005 Blackwell Publishing Ltd, Information Systems Journal 15 , 321–341 326 By its nature, trust is defined at the personal level, however, individuals in an organization may ‘share an orientation toward another organisation’ (Zaheer et al ., 1998, p. 143). The two levels are closely interrelated: • As individuals enact the relationship between organizations, their personal relations become part of the interorganizational relationship (Gulati et al ., 2000), and; • Interpersonal relations are conditioned by the legal systems and organizational role respon-sibilities that characterize relationships between organizations (Smith Ring & Van de Ven, 1994). Triggered by the limitations identified in the TCE framework to deal with the social aspects of IT use (Kumar et al ., 1998), as well as by the increasing focus in organizational research in the role that trust plays in shaping interorganizational relationships (Pavlou, 2002; Gallivan & Depledge, 2003), a number of studies have begun to address the role that trust, and in par-ticular goodwill trust, plays in the context of EM relationships. In general, existing research converges on the belief that EM affects significantly the level of trust between the actors involved (Luo, 2002; Gallivan & Depledge, 2003), although only few such studies differentiate between goodwill and risk-based trust (Pavlou, 2002; Ratmasingam, 2005). Specific institutional mechanisms such as cooperation norms and accreditation were found to support goodwill organizational trust in internet-based EM (Luo, 2002; Pavlou, 2002). Luo (2002) argues that EM also sustains personal trust through online communities and other linkages between strategically allied companies. Security services such as confidentiality and authentication mechanisms embedded in EM are also shown to support goodwill (Ratmasin-gam, 2005) interorganizational trust development (Srinivasan, 2004). Based on an extensive analysis of existing studies regarding the relation between IT use and trust in interorganiza-tional relationships, Gallivan & Depledge (2003) conclude that the use of such technologies can enhance trust between EM players, but such outcome depends on the type of IT func-tionalities used. The study suggests that whereas open sharing of confidential information sus-tains trust development, one-sided information flow, e.g. (i.e. monitoring the other party), leads to low levels of trust. Trust was also shown to influence IT use (Meier, 1995; Hart & Saunders, 1998). Hart and Saunders’ study (1998) finds that trust alleviates the risks that the other party will take advan-tage of the information exchanged in the relationships. Soliman & Janz (2004) find that with the advent of internet, trust remains a significant variable influencing the adoption and use of inter-organizational systems. Such a finding is confirmed in other studies that find that organizations are more likely to engage in internet-based exchanges with trusted parties (Vlosky et al ., 2000). However, none of these studies differentiate between the various types of trust. In conclusion, trust literature argues that there is a two-way relation between trust and EM use, although it is not always clear which type of trust do the findings refer to (Gallivan & Depledge, 2003). As trust supports collaborative relationship (Lambe et al ., 2001), it appears that collaboration is a prerequisite for EM use, and can be reinforced through the use of such technologies. Based on existing literature, this argument is summarized in Figure 2.
  • 7. Business relationships in electronic markets TR US T (Cooperative norms, accreditation, feedback) (Luo, 2002; Pavlou, 2002) Online communities; linkages between allied organisations (Luo, 2002) (reduces Depledge vulnerability) In fo rmatio n (Hart & Saunders, te c hno lo gi es 1998; Meier, 1995; Soliman & Janz, 2004; Vlosky et al., 2000) In st itutio na l me chanis ms Open info rmation sharin g ( Ga lliv an & D epl ed ge, 20 03 ) One si de d inform at io n flow Figure 2. Trust and the use of electronic markets. Se cu ri ty se rv ic es ( Ra tn as i nga m , 20 05 ; Sr in iva sa n , 2 00 4 ) TR US T + – ( Ga lliv an & D epl ed ge, 20 03 ) TR US T © 2005 Blackwell Publishing Ltd, Information Systems Journal 15 , 321–341 327 Co lla borativ e re la tions hi ps ( Ga lliv an & , 2003 ) Co mp et it iv e re la tions hi ps ( Ga lliv an & Depledge , 2003 ) Existing research suggests that both transaction costs and trust play a significant role for the way EM are used between buyers and sellers. However, whereas some TCE-based studies suggest that goodwill trust has to be included into the analysis to clarify the outcomes of EM on the nature of interorganizational relationships (Kumar et al ., 1998; Christiaanse & Kumar, 2000), there are no empirical studies in the mainstream literature that address these dimen-sions together. Moreover, research on trust in EM, with a few exceptions (Pavlou, 2002), does not differentiate explicitly between goodwill and risk-based trust, and even then, it does not address the personal and organizational dimensions together. This research addresses the role that transaction costs and goodwill trust have in explaining the outcomes of IT use on the nature of relationships developed among EM players. The research methodology that guided the empirical research is discussed in the next section. 3 . RESEARCH METHOD The empirical research follows a qualitative multi-case study research design. The choice was based on the following rationales.
  • 8. R Bunduchi © 2005 Blackwell Publishing Ltd, Information Systems Journal 15 , 321–341 328 First, the notion of ‘trust’ is multi-dimensional and difficult to measure, leading to its different conceptualizations in IS empirical studies (Gallivan & Depledge, 2002). As case studies focus on in-depth analysis (Stake, 1995), they enable the researcher to explore the complexity of the ‘trust’ concept. Second, this research understands technology as a social construct (Russell & Williams, 2002) shaped by the organizational context in which it is used (Ngwenyama & Lee, 1997). Case study design approaches enable the researcher to capture and understand the social and organizational context in which the phenomenon – the use of EM – occurs (Hussey & Hussey, 1997). Finally, following Stake (1995), the focus of this research is to search for hap-penings and not occurrences. The thrust of the study is to understand the phenomenon – the use of EM in relation to transaction costs and trust – without necessarily looking for the sta-tistical representation of the findings. This focus influences both the ontology of the research as the phenomenon cannot be abstracted from the subjective interpretations of the people who experienced them, and the research epistemology as the researcher sees herself as part of the social constructed reality, and believes that understanding the meanings that participants place on their experiences requires interactive discussions between herself and the participants. Qualitative case studies fulfil both requirements, as approach reality as socially constructed by the people involved (Creswell, 1994), and enables the researcher to interact with the respon-dents to capture their meanings and experiences (Stake, 1995). One of the common critiques of the qualitative case study design is the extent to which the findings are generalizable to populations or universes (Yin, 1994). Two arguments against this critique are explored here. First, case studies are generalizable to theoretical propositions and not to populations in the sense that case studies do not (aim to) represent a ‘sample’ of the total population. The aim of the investigator is to understand a particular issue (Stake, 1995), and not to enumerate instances in which a particular theory holds true (Yin, 1994). Second, often quantitative approaches are themselves unable to explain the limits to the domain of gener-alizability from their empirical findings. Russell & Williams (2002), e.g. argue that large-scale surveys can run to risk to inappropriately group different phenomena on the basis of features that are not necessarily the most significant. Two unrelated organizations are included into the study, as shown in Table 1: The selection of the cases follows the intensity criteria (Miles & Huberman, 1994). At the time of the study, internet-based EM were relatively a recent phenomenon and their use is not wide- Table 1. Overview of cases Characteristics OrgA OrgB Industry Petroleum Energy Role Consultancy Multi-utility Size Large Large Respondents Strategic Architect (SA); Customer Web team member (CW); Manager in Organizational Development (MOO) Supply Chain Manager (SCM), General Manager (GM), Product Manager (PrdM), IT consultant (ITC), Director of System Integration (DSI)
  • 9. Business relationships in electronic markets Table 2. Interview guide and research objectives Interview guide Research objective What are the key internet applications used to support customers and/or suppliers relationships? Identify the use and key functionalities of the EM. Are they used to the same extent with all types of partners? Explain the differences. Are there different levels of using these technologies in terms of access, amount of information, customization? Identify the characteristics of EM applications. Explain how/if their use varies depending on the characteristics of business relationships. What are the reasons for the existence of these differences? Are such differences related to interpersonal relationships, confidence in the other party, communication costs, or the risks involved in the transaction? Which are the main advantages/disadvantages in using the EM applications? Are these related to trust, cost reductions or transaction risks? Identify the outcomes of the use of EM applications on the level of trust, transaction costs and risks. EM, electronic market. © 2005 Blackwell Publishing Ltd, Information Systems Journal 15 , 321–341 329 spread (Leek et al ., 2003). It was assumed that leading companies would have not only the financial resources to acquire such technologies, but also that the expectations of their part-ners regarding EM adoption will be higher for them. Therefore, the cases were selected among the leading organizations in their industries assuming that in such cases EM usage would be most intensive, thereby providing rich information. Data collection was based on semi-structured interviews complemented with documenta-tion, which, following Remenyi et al . (2000), was primarily used to set the context for the inter-views. The interview guide followed a loose structured format, with open-ended questions that were intended to stimulate the respondents to reflect on their experiences in using the EM across different partners. The questions were mapped onto the research objectives, as shown in Table 2. Data validation was ensured through next day respondent validation, and through data tri-angulation. The information obtained during the interviews was checked, where possible, with the data gathered through documentation, and with the data provided by other interviewees. As this study seeks to combine two theoretical insights (TCE and trust) rather than to focus on the description of a case, ‘relying on a theoretical proposition’ was chosen as the strategy for data analysis. Data analysis begun gradually as the interviews proceeded. The approach allowed for a gradual refinement of the interview guide as new relevant topics appeared during the analysis and of the list of codes as the tentative conclusions were tested against new evi-dence (Miles & Huberman, 1994; Stake, 1995). Categorical aggregation (Stake, 1995), or what is called ‘open coding’ in grounded theory (Strauss & Corbin, 1990), was used to reduce the data. Coding started with a provisional list of codes created prior to the fieldwork based on the literature review. These codes are labels attached to chunks of data from the interviews, which serve to assign units of meaning to the information compiled during the study (Miles & Huberman, 1994). The initial list included two
  • 10. R Bunduchi © 2005 Blackwell Publishing Ltd, Information Systems Journal 15, 321–341 330 broad categories: (1) concepts regarding EM applications such as extent of use and type of exchange, and (2) concepts concerning the nature of relationships such as personal and orga-nizational trust, communication and coordination costs, operation risks and opportunism risks. Based on these codes, descriptive data displays were generated to explore the relation between EM use and the nature of interorganizational relationships. For example, conceptual clustered matrix were developed to explore the linkages between EM use and the nature of interorganizational relationships. Table 3 described one such matrix developed to map the out-comes of EM use on transaction costs and trust for OrgA. Such descriptive matrix displays served two purposes. First, they allowed an in-depth explo-ration of the phenomenon (the relation between EM usage and the level of trust and transaction costs). Second, displaying the data in a structured and organized fashion helped the researcher to better comprehend the phenomenon. Based on this improved understanding, the researcher was able to gradually refine the list of codes. For example, the level of customiza-tion of the EM applications was added to the EM concepts category as it recurrently appeared to reflect different usages of EM in different types of relationships. Table 3. Conceptual clustered matrix illustration EM outcomes/type of relationship Bronze (low transaction costs, organization trust present) Silver (medium transaction costs and organizational trust) Gold (high transaction costs and organizational trust) Transaction costs Replace offline with online interaction (–) Replace offline with online interaction (–) Replace offline with online interaction (–) The registration and administration of EM applications is done by the client, not by OrgB (–) The registration and administration of EM applications is done by the client, not by OrgB (–) EM applications are highly customized to the gold customers’ requirements (+) Transaction risks None None High customization of EM applications increases customers’ switching costs, and improves OrgB’s bargaining position (–) Organizational trust None EM applications support confidential information exchange with the customer (+) EM applications support confidential information exchange with the customer (+) The use of EM supports transparent service delivery to customers (+) Personal trust Replace offline with online interaction (–) Replace offline with online interaction (–) Replace offline with online interaction (–) EM, electronic market.
  • 11. Business relationships in electronic markets © 2005 Blackwell Publishing Ltd, Information Systems Journal 15, 321–341 331 The descriptive data displays were followed by explanatory data displays, which served to identify relationships among the different variables, and eventually led to conclusion drawing and verification. The explanatory data display used was causal networks. Causal network are techniques that map the relationships (arrows) between variables (nodes) in the study, where such relationships imply causality rather than just correlation (Miles & Huberman, 1994). Casual networks served to explain the relations between the emerging codes. Following Miles and Huberman’s recommendations (1994), ‘noting patterns’, and based on these patterns, ‘identifying relations between variables’ were the first steps in building causal networks. For example, during the first case, the use of EM was frequently associated with relationships involving high transaction costs. According to the interviewees, the same pattern appeared: to develop and then use EM to medi-ate the transactions with other parties required high set up costs. In order for the organization to accept such costs, high costs savings had to be achieved through the use of EM in those transactions. Because the use of EM was seen as reducing the costs of information sharing between organization, such costs saving would be higher where there is a high level of interaction going on between the organization, i.e. high transaction costs. Such pattern emerging through the data supported the drawing of the first tentative links in the causal networks. In situations in which the relations between two variables could not be precisely explained, for example between the use of EM and the duration of business relationships, ‘finding the intervening vari-ables’, that is the switching costs associated with EM use which explain why the par-ties prolong the relationship, was a useful tactic to develop the links in the network. As causal networks were constantly refined, tentative conclusions could be developed for each case. The tactic used to bring together all the patterns and relations identified across the three cases, and to develop the conclusions was ‘building a chain of evidence’, as suggested by Miles & Huberman (1994). For example, the choice to use EM and the level of trust between the parties appeared to be related in both cases. Figure 3 describes the causal network built to explain this relation. The logical chain was constructed gradually as the analysis progressed and the causal net-works were successively compared against the new evidence and refined as a result. At each step in the cases’ analysis, the links were verified as following interviewees were asked to check them. Such constant verification and refining were facilitated by the flexible approach to data collection which allowed new questions to be added and new topics to be explored during the interviews. Following Miles & Huberman (1994), casual networks narratives were developed to verify that the interpretation obtained from the casual network is plausible. The narra-tives helped to identify and explain the context, to describe the casual relationships mapped onto the network, and to explain why the variables are chained as they are. These narratives led to the development of the case outputs that are described in the next section.
  • 12. R Bunduchi Figure 3. Electronic markets (EM) use and trust. Open communication between the parties (such as through discussion forums) • The existence of trust positively Sharing confidential information (such product information) Explanation influences the use of EM between organisations as it reduces the risks that the other party will behave opportunistically and take advantage of the information exchanged. At the same time, if EM is used to share confidential information, and to support open communication, then it creates confidence in the other party thus facilitating trust building. In this way, the directions of influence among variables, i.e. trust and EM use, were identified and explained. Characteristics OrgA OrgB Role Supplier of consultancy services for the Supplier of energy services for business and home customers Ownership OrgA OrgB Functionalities Information services such as industry news and white papers, event calendar, generic discussion forums, newsletters Information services such as industry news and white papers Catalogue and consulting services and dedicated message services, shared databases Electronic billing, internet invoicing, data visualization and analysis tools, data forecasting Time in use 5 years 2 years © 2005 Blackwell Publishing Ltd, Information Systems Journal 15, 321–341 332 EM use EM USAGE - Fear that the other party will take advantage of the information exchanged through the EM TRUST BUILDING Table 4. Electronic market’s characteristics petroleum industry 4. CASE STUDIES as a dvance The characteristics of EM applications and the type of relationships included in the study are described in Table 4. The use of EM and their outcomes on the nature of customer relationships is explained in the following sections. 4.1. OrgA OrgA is a service company part of one of the leading groups in the petroleum industry. OrgA offers technical consultancy services ranging from providing the technology for extraction and exploration to developing the software for oil trading operations. Although the company was
  • 13. Business relationships in electronic markets © 2005 Blackwell Publishing Ltd, Information Systems Journal 15, 321–341 333 created in order to expand the parent company’s research and technical consultancy market, the majority of OrgA’s customers are the parent group’s operating companies. OrgA differentiates between their customers based on their belonging to the parent group (internal vs. external customers), and the duration and financial value of their contract. In gen-eral, internal customers are ‘high value companies’ with whom OrgA ‘has the biggest con-tracts’, and who are ‘highly profitable’. Such customers are labelled as ‘large customers’ with contract running a number of years, in contrast with the ‘small customers’ which are in general external customers, with a smaller financial contract, generally running out within one year. Although smaller in the financial value of their contract, external customers play a central role for OrgA because they allow the company to leverage the various products of parent group’s operating companies across a larger market, and thus reduce the costs and increase the effi-ciencies in their operations. According to the interviewees, to attract smaller customers was one of the strategic drivers that led to the creation of OrgA: [OrgA] was created in order to reduce the cost overheads by offering the opportunity to sell the technical skills provided by the company’s different business groups to a larger market. . . . from the products that the business groups have developed for large customers, we can take individual components that can be sold to smaller customers. In this way we can increase the market without increasing the costs. (SA) Part of the initiative to increase efficiencies while improving customer relationships was the development of an EM to support the delivery of consultancy services to internal and external customers alike. The services are delivered by selling to the customers a number of licences that are rights to access a particular service over the EM. There are three types of licences depending on the type of EM functionality provided to customers, as illustrated Table 5. Table 5. Services delivered over EM Type of licence Target customer Services offered Bronze licences Small customers Generic content functionality tailored to the generic requirements of a particular market sector. Services include: access to a generic library, newsletters, open and generic discussion forums, OrgA promotional information and a generic list of contacts within OrgA. Silver licences Small customers Similar content functionality as for the bronze licence, but which is customized to the requirements of individual customers. Such customized services include access to the customers’ own customized libraries, to their own list of OrgA contacts; and access to and OrgA expert which can provide confidential advice through messaging services. Gold licences Large customers In addition of the customized information services, at this level the EM provides collaborative functionality tailored to the specific needs of individual customers. The information from the customers’ databases is stored within online applications, which means that OrgA is able to review most of the data remotely, and deliver the service to such customers online through the EM EM, electronic market.
  • 14. R Bunduchi © 2005 Blackwell Publishing Ltd, Information Systems Journal 15, 321–341 334 Bronze licences are usually acquired by small customers whose contract with OrgA has ended, but who are still interested in the information services provided by OrgA. According to the interviewees, the major benefit of using the EM application is that it improves the coordination of customer relationships. Through providing online functionalities such as remote consultancy services, message services and shared databases, the EM speeds up the exchange process and decreases communication costs. Faster and cheaper communication and coordination leads to lower transaction costs. For example, the use of shared databases means that most of the consultancy work is conducted remotely. Remote work speeds up the delivery of customer services, and reduces communication and coordi-nation costs, as described in the following example: for a consultant to review all the data from a plant it took 5 days. Besides, the need to have the consultant on the site represents a big overhead for us, and being able to do this process remotely means reducing this costs overhead not only in terms of reducing the travel costs, but also in terms of a more efficient use of time for the consultant. Dur-ing this time, the consultant can also work simultaneously for somebody else, while being at the customer’s site means that during that 5 days he can work only for that customer. (SA) Whereas online interaction generally improves coordination, the delivery of functionalities such as shared databases and customized discussion forums increases maintenance costs, adding to the overall information processing costs. Nevertheless, customization is required in order to increase large customers’ switching costs and thus to restrict their choice of potential suppliers. According to one interviewee: the use of the applications will be embedded in the customer’s process: so even if the com-petitors will have the same applications, will be difficult for the clients to switch the applica-tion. The gold licences will allows us to own representation of the customer data [so it] will be difficult for the client to switch to another competitor. (SA) Higher switching costs restrict the large customers’ choice of potential suppliers. As OrgA ‘own representation of the customer data’, it finds itself in a better bargaining position in fol-lowing negotiations, which translates in lower opportunistic risk for OrgA. However, whereas opportunistic risks are lower for OrgB, they become higher for customers because of the restrictions in the number of potential suppliers. Additionally, collaborative functionalities such as shared databases enable OrgA to gain tight control over the information flows with the cus-tomer, hence reducing the operation risks associated with a misrepresentation or withholding of information. The reduction of communication and coordination costs is done at the expense of personal trust. Remote work through online consulting services, e.g. reduces the amount of face-to-face communication, hence social exchanges between OrgA and its customers. The interviewees emphasized this outcomes as a significant concern for OrgA, because the lack of personal contact with customers hinders the development of personal trust that has negative outcomes for quality of the overall customer relationship. Nevertheless, the interviewees stated that the
  • 15. Business relationships in electronic markets © 2005 Blackwell Publishing Ltd, Information Systems Journal 15, 321–341 335 customers accept the reduction in personal contact because the EM use increases their oper-ation efficiency as well. As described by one of the interviewees: The disadvantage of the [EM] is that the customers perceive that there will be less face-to-face contact [and] the customers will get less personal contact […] but in any case they usu-ally phoned the operating companies representatives, which routed them to the expert who usually answered the customers’ inquiries later in the week when he had time. On the Cus-tomer Web, the access is 24 h per day, so it is a much more efficient tool at directing ques-tions. (CW) Although reducing personal trust, the use of EM enables OrgA to support organizational trust development. First, by using customized content functionalties, OrgA uses EM to exchange confidential information with the customers, hence building customers’ confidence in the organization. Second, organizational trust development is facilitated by using the content functionalities of EM such as discussion forum which enable transparent service delivery. According to the interviewees: each service failure will contribute to decrease the customers’ trust in the channel, so in order to increase [customers] trust we need to make sure that the channel is a transparent as possible. The transparency is sustained by the existence of discussion forums. (CW) Discussion forums enable customers to communicate between themselves and with OrgA thus increasing the transparency in the relationship and building customers’ confidence in OrgA’s good faith, which can compensate for the negative outcome of a service failure. This is an illustration of risk-based trust: any service failure undermines the risk-based trust, i.e. the confidence in the ability of the partner to comply with its promises. However, goodwill trust based on confidence that the partner acts in good faith, even if he errs, can compensate for a decrease in the risk-based trust. In conclusion, EM has a range of outcomes on transaction costs and goodwill trust: in reduces personal trust but it increases organizational trust, reduces transaction cost while at the same time increasing them to enable opportunism risks reduc-tions, and finally reduces operation risks. 4.2. OrgB OrgB is a integrated multi-utility company, including gas as well as electricity businesses (although the former is significantly lower in terms of revenue than the latter), and participating in all four activities in the energy supply chain: generation, transmission, distribution and sup-ply. This study focuses on the electricity group, and the use of EM in their customers relation-ships. For the purpose of this study, customers are defined here as the end customers, i.e. the consumers of electricity such as plants, hotels and households. OrgB classifies its customers based on the financial value of their contract, i.e. their energy consumption. Residential customers include home and small businesses customers with an energy consumption less then 1 MW per year. Large business includes customers with an energy consumption higher than 1 MW per year.
  • 16. R Bunduchi © 2005 Blackwell Publishing Ltd, Information Systems Journal 15, 321–341 336 In an effort to achieve cost savings, OrgB set up the EM to support payment and deliver elec-tricity services with both residential and large business customers. The services delivered over EM depend on the type of customer, as illustrated in Table 6. OrgB emphasizes cost savings as the principal outcome of using the EM with both residen-tial and large business customers. As one respondent mentioned: At the end of the day, the whole scope of the technology is to reduce costs, either by reduc-ing personal contact, which unfortunately means less people, or by allowing the company to move quickly, and achieve more flexibility. (GM) Cost reductions are achieve through functionalities such as electronic billing and internet invoicing services which significantly reduce paper- and phone-based communication costs, while at the same time reducing the number of personnel dealing with customers. These reduc-tions are illustrated by the following response: the [EM] produces cost savings: it reduces the cost to serve the customer. For the online cus-tomers, we don’t send any paper bill anymore, all the correspondence is done online. So there are the cost savings for the paper billing. . . . All the benefits come from the cost sav-ings, not only paper, but also the reduction in the personnel that deals with the customers. There is no need for so many people anymore to answer the phone, or look for information, as everything is handled online. (PM) Electronic market commercial functionalities such as electronic billing and internet invoicing enhance the transparency of service delivery enabling online customers to check the level of their energy consumption whenever they want. They can also pay the bill online whenever they choose during a quarter, rather than having to wait for OrgB to issue the bill at the end of the quarter. This reduces customers’ misunderstandings regarding the amount of energy con-sumption, which according to the interviewees is commonplace when the customer receives a paper-based bill. As these misunderstandings represent that largest part of all communication Table 6. Electronic market functionalities in OrgB Type of customer Services offered Residential customer Offers primarily commerce functionality in the form of online billing which allows the customer to create and pay the bill online. It provides limited information services such as contact information. Large business Internet invoicing which enables customers to analyse the invoices online or download the information directly into internal systems. Peak demand forecast which provides customers with predicted demand forecasts during the winter months (November – February). This enables the customers to identify periods of expected high demand and potentially high charges. Data services which provides information visualization, analysis and standardized report tools to the customers. Content functionalities such as demos, contact information, industry news and papers.
  • 17. Business relationships in electronic markets © 2005 Blackwell Publishing Ltd, Information Systems Journal 15, 321–341 337 between customers and OrgB, the use of EM means not only cheaper communication (because online communication is cheaper than paper- and phone-based communication), but also less communication between OrgB and its customers that further reduces the communi-cation, and improves coordination. As described by one respondent: [online customers] can create the bill whenever they want. They don’t have to wait 90 days, which is the time it takes us to send out the bill to paper-based customers. The [energy] con-sumption is much more visible for them online. Online customers can also phone or send us an e-mail if they have any questions . . . [there is] less communication than with offline cus-tomers. The type of messages that we have with online customers is if something is not working, or if they want to change something, but the rest of the problems are avoided with online customers. (PM) In contrast with OrgA, no evidence was found in this case of an increase in the level of trans-action costs as a result of EM use. One explanation may be the limited experience with the deployment of EM, as EM was launched by OrgB only 2 years ago. As mentioned by one respondent, whereas commerce functionalities such as electronic bill-ing enable less and cheaper communication with the customer, and ease the coordination of the overall relationship, it also reduces personal contact that inhibits personal trust develop-ment. Personal trust requires social exchanges between the parties involved in a relationship, and such exchanges are more likely to happen over the phone and face-to-face than through online communication (email). As the respondents argued: E-mail doesn’t let you build a personal relationship, or develop trust in the person you com-municate with. (RMTM) Whereas in the case of residential customers such social exchanges were already limited (because only phone- and paper-based channels were open to them), the decline in social exchanges is higher for large businesses customers who were dealt directly and personally by an OrgB representative. None of the functionalities provided through the EM support (or inhibit) organizational trust building. No evidence was found to suggest that OrgB is concerned with or attempts to support goodwill trust through the use of EM. At the same time, the respondents did not perceived any changes in the level of transaction risks as a result of EM use with the customers. 4.3. Discussion The two case studies analyse two different models of EM use in interorganizational relation-ships, a collaborative model in the first case, and a transactional model in the second case. In both models, a major outcome of EM use is transaction costs reductions, sustained through commerce functionalities such as remote consultancy services, electronic billing as well as collaborative functionalities such as dedicated messaging service. Such an outcome supports the large body of TCE-based studies which argue that IT in general, EM in particular lowers transaction costs (Malone et al., 1987; Bakos, 1991; Hart & Estrin, 1991).
  • 18. R Bunduchi © 2005 Blackwell Publishing Ltd, Information Systems Journal 15, 321–341 338 In the collaborative model, we found that EM use can increase communication and information processing costs. The explanation relates to the trade-offs involved in collabo-rative EM use. These trade-offs refer to the choices that the organization makes between the different outcomes of EM functionalities on its objectives. Whilst the use of content and collaborative functionalities such as customized discussion forums and shared data bases adds to the level of transaction costs, they also increase customers’ switching costs leading to lower opportunism risks. As such transaction risks are higher in collaborative relationships (Clemons et al., 1993), the organization places more emphasis on the ability of EM to reduce transaction risks, than the ability of EM to reduce transaction costs. Con-sequently, the owner of the EM (in our case the supplier) assesses the different out-comes that EM functionalities have on its objectives, and selects to use those that best achieve its objectives. A similar trade-off in the collaborative model relates to transaction costs and personal trust. Commerce functionalities such as electronic billing and remote consultancy services are used to reduce transaction costs, although they hinder personal trust. The deliberate choice to reduce personal trust, although a significant concern for OrgA as it hampers collaboration in the relationships suggests that personal trust plays an inferior role to organizational trust in supporting the collaborative nature of interorganizational relationships. This support Zaheer et al’s (1998) study which found that the influence of personal trust on the nature of a business relationship is limited and subordinated to organizational trust. Consequently, in collaborative relationships, the use of EM is marked by trade-offs between different functionalities. Organizations balance their objectives, and assess the outcomes that the content, commerce and collaborative EM functionalities have on these objectives. This bal-ancing between the different outcomes of EM functionalities on the overall objectives of the organizations governs the way organizations use EM applications in their collaborative relationships. In contrast, in the transaction models, transaction costs reduction is the primary intended outcome of EM use. The reduction in personal trust which occurs as a result of commerce func-tionality such as electronic billing is acknowledged as a side-effect of EM use, but is not con-sidered as a significant outcome. As the relationships are transactional, personal trust is not a relevant variable in the exchange (Morgan & Hunt, 1994; Lambe et al., 2001). Therefore, the use of transactional EM does not involve trade-offs, as the primary focus is on deploying com-merce functionalities to reduce transaction cost. The study also finds that as suggested by Clemons et al. (1993), EM use lowers transaction risks in the collaborative model. Collaborative functionalities such as shared databases reduce operational risks by enabling better control over the information exchanged, whereas the ability to customize the EM to increase the partner’s switching costs improves the bargaining position of the organization developing the EM and thus reduces opportunism risks. Evidence that EM support organizational goodwill trust is also found in the collaborative model, through the use of collaborative functionalities such as shared databases, and through the use of content functionalities such as discussion forums. The explanation of the later is that such information sharing enables the organization to build and maintain a sense community
  • 19. Business relationships in electronic markets © 2005 Blackwell Publishing Ltd, Information Systems Journal 15, 321–341 339 within its customer users which enhances trust in the organization that manages such com-munity, as suggested by Luo, (2002). In line with previous studies (Hart & Saunders, 1998; Gal-livan & Depledge, 2003), in the collaborative model, EM use was found to sustain organization trust through increasing the amount of confidential information exchanged between parties and through enhancing the transparency of the service. 5. CONCLUSIONS AND FUTURE RESEARCH This article investigated the outcomes that EM use has on collaborative and transactional rela-tionships between buyer and seller organizations by addressing the transaction cost and trust dimensions together. The study is based on a multi-case study research design that has a number of limitations. First, the study includes only dyadic relationships between buyers and sellers that are analysed only from the perspective of the organization under study. However, the objectives that orga-nizations pursue in their interorganizational relationships and the trade-offs that govern the use of EM in these relationships might depend on the wider internet-worked context in which orga-nizations currently operate (Castells, 2000). Additionally, the perspective of the other party regarding the outcomes of EM use and the trade-offs that they are prepared to accept are not taken into account. For this reason, the study provides only a limited view on the EM use in interorganizational relationships, and has to be extended by assessing the objectives and the trade-offs that both partners have to make in their usage of EM. Secondly, the nature of ser-vices transacted over the EM in the two cases is different which might affect the level of trans-action costs. Consequently, future research is required to test the wider applicability of the findings. Such studies should include a wider range of organizations, should address the net-work level of EM use and, most importantly, should include all the partners involved in a par-ticular instance of EM use. Notwithstanding these limitations, this study bring three significant contributions to the IS literature. First, a thorough investigation of the role that trust together with transaction costs have for the use of EM is lacking from the mainstream literature, although there have been claims that these dimensions should be addressed together (Steinfield et al., 1995; Kumar et al., 1998; Christiaanse & Kumar, 2000). Relying on two in-depth studies of collaborative and transactional uses of EM, this study explains the outcomes of EM use on collaborative and transactional buyer–seller relationships by addressing these dimensions together. Second, the study found that the collaborative use of EM is shaped by the trade-offs that organizations make between the outcomes that different EM functionalities have on their col-laborative objectives. Organizations assesses the outcomes that different content, commerce and collaboration EM functionalities have on their objectives relating to transaction costs and trust, and selects to use those that allow the best way to achieve them. In contrast, such trade-offs are not involved in transactional uses of EM, as the main focus here is to achieve trans-action cost reductions.
  • 20. R Bunduchi © 2005 Blackwell Publishing Ltd, Information Systems Journal 15, 321–341 340 Finally, the study provides empirical support to the assertion that the TCE framework is lim-ited in its ability to account for collaborative uses of EM, as suggested in previous research (Kumar et al., 1998; Markus & Christiaanse, 2003). REFERENCES Backhaus, K. & Buschken, J. (1997) What do we know about business-to-business interactions? – a synopsis of empirical research on buyer–seller interactions. In: Rela-tionships and Networks in International Markets, Gemunden, H.G., Ritter, T. & Walter, A. (eds), pp. 13– 33. Elsevier, Pergamon, UK. Bakos, Y. (1991) A strategic analysis of electronic market-places. MIS Quarterly, 15, 295–310. Bakos, Y. (1998) The emerging role of electronic market-places on the internet. Communications of the ACM, 41, 35–42. Bakos, Y. & Brynjolfsson, E. (1997) Organizational part-nership and the virtual corporation. In: Information Tech-nology and Industrial Competitiveness: How Information Technology Shapes Competition, Kemerer, C.F. (ed.), pp. 1–18. Kluwer, Amsterdam, the Netherlands. Castells, M. (2000) The Information Age: Economy, Soci-ety, and Culture. Vol. 1: The Rise of the Network Econ-omy. Blackwell Publishers, Oxford, UK. Christiaanse, E. & Kumar, K. (2000) ICT-enabled coordi-nation of dynamic supply webs. International Journal of Physical Distribution and Logistics, 30, 268–285. Christiaanse, E., van Diepen, T. & Damsgaard, J. (2004) Proprietary versus internet technologies and the adop-tion and impact of electronic marketplaces. Journal of Strategic Information Systems, 13, 151–165. Clemons, E.K., Reddi, S.P. & Row, M.C. (1993) The impact of information technology on the organization of economic activity: the ‘Move to the middle’ hypothe-sis. Journal of Management Information Systems, 10, 9–35. Creswell, J.W. (1994) Research Design Qualitative and Quantitative Approaches. SAGE, Thousand Oaks, CA, USA. Dyer, J.H., Cho, D.S. & Chu, W. (1998) Strategic supplier segmentation: the next ‘Best Practice’ in supply chain management. California Management Review, 40, 57– 77. Easton, G. (1997) Industrial Networks: A review. In: Under-standing Business Markets Ford, D. (ed.), pp. 102–128. The Dryden Press, London, UK. Gallivan, M.J. & Depledge, G. (2003) Trust, control and the role of interorganizational systems in electronic partnership. Information Systems Journal, 13, 159– 190. Garcia-Dastugue, S.J. & Lambert, D.M. (2003) Internet-enabled coordination in the supply chain. Industrial Mar-keting Management, 32, 251–263. Geun Lee, H. & Clark, T.H. (1996/97) Market process re-eingineering through electronic market systems. Oppor-tunities and Challenges Journal of Management Information Systems, 13, 113–136. Gulati, R., Nohria, N. & Zaheer, A. (2000) Strategic net-works. Strategic Management Journal, 21, 203–215. Hart, P. & Estrin, D. (1991) Inter-organization networks, Computer integration, and shifts in interdependence: the case of the semiconductor industry. ACM Transactions on Information Systems, 9, 370–398. Hart, P.J. & Saunders, C.S. (1998) Emerging electronic partnerships: antecedents and dimensions of EDI use from the supplier’s perspective. Journal of Management Information Systems, 14, 87–111. Hussey, J. & Hussey, R. (1997) Business Research. Mac- Millan Business, London, UK. Kraut, R., Steinfield, C., Chan, A., Butler, B. & Hoag, A. (1998) Coordination and virtualisation: the role of elec-tronic networks and personal relationships. Journal of Computer-Mediated Communications, 3, 1–34. Kumar, K. & van Dissel, H. (1996) Sustainable collabora-tion: managing conflict and cooperation in interorganisa-tional systems MIS Quarterly, 20, 279–300. Kumar, K., Dissel, H. & Bielli, P. (1998) The merchant of Prato – revisited: toward a third rationality of information systems. MIS Quarterly, 22, 199–227. Lambe, C.J., Wittmann, C.M. & Spekman, R.E. (2001) Social exchange theory and research on business-to-business relational exchange. Journal of Business to Business Marketing, 8, 1–36. Leek, S., Turnbull, P.W. & Naude, P. (2003) How is infor-mation technology affecting business relationships? Results from a UK survey. Industrial Marketing Manage-ment, 32, 119–126.
  • 21. Business relationships in electronic markets © 2005 Blackwell Publishing Ltd, Information Systems Journal 15, 321–341 341 Luo, X. (2002) Trust production and privacy concerns on the Internet. A framework based on relationship market-ing and social exchange theory. Industrial Marketing Management, 31, 111–118. Malone, T.W., Yates, J. & Benjamin, R.I. (1987) Electronic markets and electronic hierarchies. Communications of the ACM, 30, 484–497. Markus, M.L. & Christiaanse, E. (2003) Adoption and impact of collaboration electronic marketplaces. Informa-tion Systems and E-Business Management, 1, 139–155. Meier, J. (1995) The importance of relationship manage-ment in establishing successful interorganisational systems. Journal of Strategic Information Systems, 4, 135–148. Miles, M.B. & Huberman, A.M. (1994) Qualitative Data Analyisis: an Expanded Sourcebook. Sage Publications, Thousand Oaks, CA, USA. Morgan, R.M. & Hunt, S.D. (1994) The commitment-trust theory of relationships marketing. Journal of Marketing, 58, 20–38. Ngwenyama, O.K. & Lee, A.S. (1997) Communication rich-ness in electronic mail: critical social theory and the con-textuality of meaning. MIS Quarterly, 21, 145–167. Nooteboom, B. (1996) Trust, opportunism and gover-nance: a process and control model. Organization Stud-ies, 17, 985–1010. Pavlou, P.A. (2002) Institution-based trust in interorgani-zational exchange relationships: the role of online B2B marketplaces on trust formation. Journal of Strategic Information Systems, 11, 215–243. Ratnasingam, P. (2005) Trust in inter-organizational exchanges: a case study in business to business elec-tronic commerce. Decision Support Systems, 39, 524– 544. Remenyi, D., Williams, B., Money, A. & Swartz, E. (2000) Doing Research in Business and Management. Sage Publications, London, UK. Russell, S. & Williams, R. (2002) Social shaping of tech-nology: frameworks, findings and implications for policy with glossary of social shaping concepts. In: Shaping Technology, Guiding Policy, Sorensen, K.H. & Williams, R. (eds), pp. 37–132. Edward Elgar, Chetlenham, UK. Sako, M. (1992) Prices, Quality and Trust: Inter-Firm Rela-tions in Britain and Japan. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, UK. Smith Ring, P. & Van de Ven, A.H. (1992) Structuring cooperative relationships between organisations. Strate-gic Management Journal, 13, 483–498. Smith Ring, P. & Van de Ven, A.H. (1994) Developmental processes of cooperative interorganizational relation-ships. Academy of Management Review, 19, 90–118. Soliman, K.S. & Janz, B.D. (2004) An exploratory study to identify the critical factors affecting the decision to estab-lish Internet-based interorganizational information sys-tems. Information and Management, 41, 696–706. Srinivasan, S. (2004) Role of trust in e-business success. Information Management and Computer Security, 12, 66–72. Stake, R.E. (1995) The Art of Case Study Research. Sage Publications, Thousand Oaks, CA, USA. Steinfield, C., Kraut, R. & Plummer, A. (1995) The impact of interorganizational networks on buyer–seller relation-ships. Journal of Computer-Mediated Communications, 1, 1–17. Strauss, A. & Corbin, J. (1990) Basics of Qualitative Research Grounded Theory Procedures and Tech-niques. Sage Publications, Thousand Oaks, CA, USA. Vlosky, R.P., Fontenot, R. & Blalock, L. (2000) Extranets: impacts on business practices and relationships. Journal of Business and Industrial Marketing, 15, 438–457. Williamson, O.E. (1986) Economic Organization Firms, Markets and Policy Control. New York University Press, New York, USA. Williamson, O.E. (1993) Calculativeness, trust, and eco-nomic organisation. Journal of Law and Economics, 36, 453–486. Yin, R.K. (1994) Case Study Research Design and Meth-ods. Sage Publication, Thousand Oaks, CA, USA. Zaheer, A., McEvily, B. & Perrone, V. (1998) Does trust matter? Exploring the effects of interorganizational and interpersonal trust on performance. Organization Sci-ence, 9, 141–159. Biography Raluca Bunduchi is a lecturer in Management at the Busi-ness School, Aberdeen University. Prior to this, she worked as a Research Fellow in the Research Centre for Social Sciences at the University of Edinburgh. She studied for her PhD in the Department of Management Science at Strathclyde Business School in Glasgow examining the use of internet technologies and their implications for the nature of business relationships within and across organi-zational boundaries. Raluca Bunduchi can be reached at bunduchi@yahoo.com