SlideShare a Scribd company logo
1 of 178
Global value chains, rising power firms and economic and
social upgrading
falseLee, Joonkoo; Gereffi, GaryAuthor Information
. Critical Perspectives on International Business;
Bradford11.3/4 (2015): 319-339.
1. Full text
2. Full text - PDF
3. Abstract/Details
Abstract
Translate AbstractUndo Translation TranslateUndo Translation
Press the Escape key to close
FromTo
Translate
Translation in progress...
[[missing key: loadingAnimation]]
The full text may take 40-60 seconds to translate; larger
documents may take longer.
Cancel
OverlayEnd
Purpose
- The purpose of this paper is to introduce the global value
chain (GVC) approach to understand the relationship between
multinational enterprises (MNEs) and the changing patterns of
global trade, investment and production, and its impact on
economic and social upgrading. It aims to illuminate how GVCs
can advance our understanding about MNEs and rising power
(RP) firms and their impact on economic and social upgrading
in fragmented and dispersed global production systems.
Design/methodology/approach
- The paper reviews the GVC literature focusing on two
conceptual elements of the GVC approach, governance and
upgrading, and highlights three key recent developments in
GVCs: concentration, regionalization and synergistic
governance.
Findings
- The paper underscores the complicated role of GVCs in
shaping economic and social upgrading for emerging
economies, RP firms and developing country firms in general.
Rising geographic and organizational concentration in GVCs
leads to the uneven distribution of upgrading opportunities in
favor of RP firms, and yet economic upgrading may be elusive
even for the most established suppliers because of power
asymmetry with global buyers. Shifting end markets and the
regionalization of value chains can benefit RP firms by
presenting alternative markets for upgrading. Yet, without
further upgrading, such benefits may be achieved at the expense
of social downgrading. Finally, the ineffectiveness of private
standards to achieve social upgrading has led to calls for
synergistic governance through the cooperation of private,
public and social actors, both global and local.
Originality/value
- The paper illuminates how the GVC approach and its key
concepts can contribute to the critical international business and
RP firms literature by examining the latest dynamics in GVCs
and their impacts on economic and social development in
developing countries.
Purpose
- The purpose of this paper is to introduce the global value
chain (GVC) approach to understand the relationship between
multinational enterprises (MNEs) and the changing patterns of
global trade, investment and production, and its impact on
economic and social upgrading. It aims to illuminate how GVCs
can advance our understanding about MNEs and rising power
(RP) firms and their impact on economic and social upgrading
in fragmented and dispersed global production systems.
Design/methodology/approach
- The paper reviews the GVC literature focusing on two
conceptual elements of the GVC approach, governance and
upgrading, and highlights three key recent developments in
GVCs: concentration, regionalization and synergistic
governance.
Findings
- The paper underscores the complicated role of GVCs in
shaping economic and social upgrading for emerging
economies, RP firms and developing country firms in general.
Rising geographic and organizational concentration in GVCs
leads to the uneven distribution of upgrading opportunities in
favor of RP firms, and yet economic upgrading may be elusive
even for the most established suppliers because of power
asymmetry with global buyers. Shifting end markets and the
regionalization of value chains can benefit RP firms by
presenting alternative markets for upgrading. Yet, without
further upgrading, such benefits may be achieved at the expense
of social downgrading. Finally, the ineffectiveness of private
standards to achieve social upgrading has led to calls for
synergistic governance through the cooperation of private,
public and social actors, both global and local.
Originality/value
- The paper illuminates how the GVC approach and its key
concepts can contribute to the critical international business and
RP firms literature by examining the latest dynamics in GVCs
and their impacts on economic and social development in
developing countries.
You have requested "on-the-fly" machine translation of selected
content from our databases. This functionality is provided
solely for your convenience and is in no way intended to replace
human translation. Show full disclaimer
Neither ProQuest nor its licensors make any representations or
warranties with respect to the translations. The translations are
automatically generated "AS IS" and "AS AVAILABLE" and
are not retained in our systems. PROQUEST AND ITS
LICENSORS SPECIFICALLY DISCLAIM ANY AND ALL
EXPRESS OR IMPLIED WARRANTIES, INCLUDING
WITHOUT LIMITATION, ANY WARRANTIES FOR
AVAILABILITY, ACCURACY, TIMELINESS,
COMPLETENESS, NON-INFRINGMENT,
MERCHANTABILITY OR FITNESS FOR A PARTICULAR
PURPOSE. Your use of the translations is subject to all use
restrictions contained in your Electronic Products License
Agreement and by using the translation functionality you agree
to forgo any and all claims against ProQuest or its licensors for
your use of the translation functionality and any output derived
there from. Hide full disclaimer Translations powered by LEC.
Translations powered by LEC.
Full Text
· Translate Full textUndo Translation TranslateUndo
Translation
Press the Escape key to close
FromTo
Translate
Translation in progress...
[[missing key: loadingAnimation]]
The full text may take 40-60 seconds to translate; larger
documents may take longer.
Cancel
OverlayEnd
· Turn on search term navigationTurn on search term navigation
· Jump to first hit
Listen
Introduction
With the growing influence of multinational enterprises (MNEs)
in the global economy, their role in promoting economic growth
in developing countries has been hotly debated. In the
international business (IB) literature, the mainstream approach
tends to assume the positive impact of MNEs on economic
development. The general consensus is that foreign direct
investment and the presence of MNEs will lead to economic
development in the host country through the spillover of capital,
technology, skills and knowledge (Ghauri and Yamin, 2009;
Meyer, 2004). Economic development is considered as a
byproduct of MNE operations, not a core objective of MNEs.
However, there has been weak evidence to support the spillover
argument (Farole and Winkler, 2014; Oetzel and Doh, 2009).
This has led recent IB scholarship to challenge such arguments,
shifting attention to a more realistic picture of the effects of
MNEs on economic and social development. This critical
perspective casts light on the potential damaging effects of
MNEs on economic development through the "race to the
bottom" and "immiserizing growth". At the same time, with
positive development outcomes no longer guaranteed as a
byproduct of MNE operations, this critical perspective
questions why MNEs should be concerned about development in
the host country and the potential constraints they may face in
trying to achieve it (Gifford et al. , 2010; Meyer, 2004; Yamin
and Sinkovics, 2009).
Despite this renewed interest from a critical perspective, the IB
literature has yet to develop a systematic understanding of the
relationship between MNEs and developing economies (Ghauri
and Yamin, 2009). A more robust conceptual framework is
needed, particularly because of the rapid reorganization of
industrial production on the global scale, as well as the varied
ways in which the MNE orchestrates its value chains across
countries and regions, and inside and outside its organizational
boundaries (Buckley, 2009; De Marchi et al. , 2014). This
controversy has been accentuated by the recent global economic
recession (Cattaneo et al. , 2010; Gereffi, 2014). This reopens
the question of how these changes in the global and
organizational environment of MNEs (re)shape the possibilities
and constraints of economic and social development in
developing countries (Buckley and Ghauri, 2004).
As a contribution to this framework-building effort, this article
introduces the global value chain (GVC) approach to better
understand the relationship between MNEs and the changing
patterns of global trade, investment and production, as well as
the impact of MNEs on local upgrading efforts in developing
economies. The GVC literature is uniquely positioned to
provide a bridge between the IB and development literatures.
The GVC approach originated with issues like why some
countries are more successful in achieving economic
development than others, and these questions have recently
expanded into the social impact of economic upgrading
(Barrientos et al. , 2011; Gereffi and Kaplinsky, 2001; Gereffi
and Korzeniewicz, 1994; Lee et al. , 2011). Unlike other
streams of development studies, however, the primary focus of
GVC analysis is on firms and the governance of inter-firm
relations, thereby providing an entry point for investigating
networked forms of MNEs and other IB concerns (Bair, 2005;
Lee, 2010 for reviews).
This article will show how firms that are organized in GVCs
affect economic and social upgrading in both dispersed and
concentrated production systems, and it will also identify new
trends in the GVC system that should be more fully
incorporated in the critical IB literature. First, we introduce the
GVC approach by highlighting two key concepts - governance
and upgrading - that are the building blocks of this framework.
Second, we discuss the implications for emerging economies
and rising power (RP) firms of three significant developments
in post-crisis GVCs: geographic and organizational
concentration, shifting end markets and regionalization and the
rise of standards and synergistic governance. We conclude with
some summary reflections on how the GVC approach adds value
to the IB literature.
Governance and upgrading: complementary perspectives on the
global economy
A GVC refers to "the full range of activities that firms and
workers perform to bring a specific product from its conception
to its end use and beyond" (Gereffi and Fernandez-Stark, 2011).
Generally, it includes research and development (R & D),
design, production, sales and marketing, consumption and
recycling. A GVC approach views the global economy as a
complex network linking together suppliers and buyers that are
integrated and driven by MNEs as lead firms. GVCs have
become an integral part of the global economy, reshaping the
traditional patterns of international production and trade.
According to UNCTAD (2013, pp. 133-135), 80 per cent of
world trade now passes through GVCs, and the developing
country share in global value-added trade doubled from 20 to 40
per cent between 1990 and 2010. While measuring employment
creation by GVCs is difficult, one study of 39 countries
estimates that GVCs have generated 88 million jobs (Jiang and
Milberg, 2013).
The GVC approach provides a holistic view of global industries
from the vantage point of two key concepts: governance and
upgrading. Governance highlights the top-down process
whereby lead firms integrate geographically and
organizationally dispersed economic activities. While GVC
analysis shares a firm-centric approach with the IB literature,
its focus goes beyond the hierarchical governance of a firm (i.e.
vertical integration and headquarter-subunit relations), and
extends to various forms of contractual and relational
coordination between independent companies that span
international borders (De Marchi et al. , 2014). In addition to
these corporate forms of governance, the GVC approach also
pays attention to public and social governance and the
institutional factors that shape them (Gereffi et al. , 2005;
Mayer, 2014).
The concept of upgrading focuses on the bottom-up strategies
used by countries, regions and local firms to maintain or
improve their positions and outcomes in the global economy.
The GVC approach does not simply assume that integration to
GVCs leads to economic upgrading through positive spillovers,
but seeks to establish under what conditions, particularly under
what GVC governance arrangements, upgrading (or
downgrading) is likely to occur (Barrientos et al. , 2011;
Humphrey and Schmitz, 2002)[1].
GVC governance: driving, coordinating and normalizing
GVC governance is defined as "authority and power
relationships that determine how financial, material, and human
resources are allocated and flow within a chain" (Gereffi, 1994,
p. 97). Production processes in the globalization era have been
fundamentally restructured through offshoring and outsourcing.
Unlike vertical integration where internal control and corporate
fiat are used to solve coordination problems within the
boundary of a firm, global outsourcing involves governance
mechanisms that span the activities of multiple firms across
national boundaries.
The GVC literature highlights three aspects of GVC
governance: driving, coordinating and normalizing (Ponte and
Sturgeon, 2014). "Governance as driving" focuses on the lead
firms in diverse global industries whose market power and
technological or marketing assets allow them to set the
performance criteria in terms of price, quality and delivery
standards that shape the behavior of their suppliers. The
distinction between "producer-driven" and "buyer-driven"
chains is seminal: it asserts that two types of lead firms - large
manufacturers and global buyers (i.e. retailers, brands and
supermarkets) - drive supply chains differently and pose distinct
challenges for chain entry and upgrading (Gereffi, 1994; Gereffi
and Lee, 2012). For example, while in buyer-driven chains,
global buyers like Nike tend to own few or no factories and
instead focus on product design, branding and marketing, their
governance power extends well beyond their main contractors as
their orders and specifications travel down to hundreds of
lower-tier suppliers in their supply chain[2] (Donaghu and
Barff, 1990).
"Governance as coordination" highlights the varied forms of
inter-firm linkages in GVCs. GVCs consist of multiple linkages
that connect suppliers and buyers. The GVC approach extends
the "market-hierarchy" dichotomy in transaction cost economics
(Williamson, 1985) by offering a more elaborate typology of
enduring inter-firm networks that characterize international
supply chains. For example, Gereffi et al. (2005) identify five
types of GVC governance: market (arms-length transactions)
and hierarchy (vertical integration), along with three distinctive
network-types (modular, relational and captive). The GVC
perspective asserts that not all network forms of governance are
alike. Also, it posits that the type of GVC governance that
arises in a specific chain depends on a combination of three key
factors: the complexity of inter-firm transactions, the
codifiability of the transactions and suppliers' capability to meet
buyers' requirements. Thus, the nature of transactions defines
the form of governance that affects upgrading of the parties
involved.
While "governance as driving" relates to the entire chain
(macro-level) and "governance as coordination" involves
linkages at specific junctures in the chain (micro-level),
"governance as normalizing" deals with the meso-level of GVC
governance. Particularly, GVC scholars pay attention to various
standards and relevant normative frameworks that shape the
overall conditions of GVC participation and upgrading (Gibbon
and Ponte, 2008; Ponte and Gibbon, 2005). Such standards
allow a normative, or commonly agreed, element of
coordination, such as defining rules, conventions and conditions
of chain participation, to travel along the chain from one node
to another, working as a mechanism "re-aligning a given
practice to be compatible with a standard or norm" (Ponte and
Sturgeon, 2014, p. 206).
Recent GVC research has highlighted the interaction of multiple
forms of governance. Challenging the existing notion of a
unipolar structure of governance, where one set of firms -
buyers or producers - has dominant power to govern, newer
studies feature the role of bipolar or multi-polar GVC
governance, where more complicated patterns of power relations
emerge between lead firms in GVCs (Fold, 2002; Islam, 2008;
Kawakami, 2011). For example, in the automobile industry, one
of the paradigmatic producer-driven chains, the rise of "mega
suppliers" is challenging the pre-eminent role of the carmakers
as lead firms and altering the balance of power in the industry
(Foy, 2014). There are now 16 major car manufacturers that sell
more than 1 million vehicles per year, but those cars are built
from parts supplied by just ten major component makers[3],
meaning that auto assemblers are now reliant on a small cadre
of mega suppliers who each sell parts to rival assemblers.
Although the automakers are still considerably larger than the
mega suppliers in sales, the latter are more profitable than the
companies they sell to[4]. While mega suppliers are in a
position to bargain more effectively with global automakers[5],
the latter remain in the driver's seat in terms of overall
governance of the automotive value chain because they
determine when, where and at what price they will sell fully
assembled vehicles to customers around the world.
Upgrading: economic and social dimensions
Upgrading refers to "a process of improving the ability of a firm
or an economy to move to a more profitable and/or
technologically sophisticated capital- and skill-intensive
economic niche" (Gereffi, 1999, pp. 51-52). The concept
originated in the observation that what matters for a country's
development was less the overall level of industrialization than
the type of chain activities they were involved in. In other
words, a country or firm obtains bigger gains when they move
up the value chain into higher value-added chains or nodes
(Gereffi and Kaplinsky, 2001).
A central argument of the GVC approach is that the type of
governance structure significantly affects upgrading outcomes.
Humphrey and Schmitz (2002) specify four types of upgrading,
representing different "niches" where upgrading takes place:
Process upgrading : Making production processes more efficient
by reorganizing the production system and using advanced
technology;
Product upgrading : Moving into more sophisticated, or high-
value, product lines;
Functional upgrading : Occupying more profitable functional
nodes within a chain; and
Chain upgrading : Diversifying into more profitable value
chains.
GVC studies have found that product and process upgrading are
facilitated by learning from global buyers, whereas global
buyers do not necessarily facilitate functional upgrading
(Schmitz, 2004). For example, in Brazil's Sinos Valley shoe
cluster, tight coordination by foreign buyers created favorable
conditions for local suppliers to achieve product and process
upgrading (Bazan and Navas-Alemán, 2004). However,
upgrading to higher-value activities like branding and design
was constrained by a captive mode of governance (Giuliani et
al. , 2005; Lee and Chen, 2000). Functional upgrading was out
of reach when global buyers were reluctant to support it, or
actively blocked it out of concern that it might bring greater
competition (Bazan and Navas-Alemán, 2004). Similarly,
American buyers contributed to the process and product
upgrading of local blue jeans producers in Torreon, Mexico,
giving rise to full-package production. Yet, more extensive
functional upgrading did not take place because of the risks that
such upgrading posed for MNE lead firms (Bair and Gereffi,
2001).
In much of the GVC literature, there has been an implicit
presumption that economic upgrading would lead to social
gains, i.e. the improvement of the well-being of workers in the
chains. Yet, recent evidence suggests that economic upgrading
is often not accompanied by social upgrading, and indeed, it can
worsen social conditions (Lee et al. , 2011). Social upgrading
refers to the process of improvement in the rights and
entitlements of workers as social actors and enhances the
quality of their employment (Barrientos et al. , 2011). A series
of studies from the Capturing the Gains research program[6]
have found that upgrading is segmented. For example, regular
workers may benefit from higher wages and strong labor
standards as a result of economic upgrading, while many others,
particularly women and migrant workers, are put in highly
flexible, unprotected and insecure work. Poor jobs are fuelled
by low productivity, subcontracting and suppliers struggling to
meet buyers' requirements on product quality as well as social
and environmental standards. Progress made in measurable
standards (e.g. the size and type of employment, wages and
working hours) may not extend to enabling rights (e.g. freedom
of association and the right to collective bargaining), with many
export sectors suffering an extremely low level of unionization
(Barrientos et al. , 2012).
In short, with the concepts of governance and upgrading, the
GVC approach provides a firm-based, network-centric view of
how MNEs as global lead firms affect economic and social
development. The role of MNEs in promoting or inhibiting
development extends beyond their hierarchical boundary to a
series of GVC linkages they govern in various ways: driving,
coordinating and normalizing. The GVC literature also suggests
that the scope and speed of upgrading and the gains from it
largely depend on a firm's position and the types of governance
in place in the GVC, and economic upgrading does not
necessarily lead to social upgrading.
Changing GVC dynamics and the impacts on emerging
economies and RP firms
The global economy has undergone significant changes over the
past two decades, and the emerging economies have been clear
winners. Whereas the share of high-income countries in total
value added that was generated in all manufacturing GVCs
declined from 74 per cent in 1995 to 56 per cent in 2008, and
the share of Japan and the East Asian newly industrializing
economies (NIEs) declined from 21 to 11 per cent, emerging
economies have increased their shares of value added in
manufacturing by 18 per cent. China alone is responsible for
half of this increase, with its global share rising rapidly from 4
to 13 per cent, but value added shares also increased in other
emerging economies, including Brazil, Russia, India and
Mexico (Timmer et al. , 2014, p. 109). During this same period,
42 million manufacturing jobs were added in China, 20 million
in India, 6 million in Brazil and 2 million in Mexico (Timmer et
al. , 2014, p. 112).
More recently, the global recession of the late 2000s
precipitated sharp shifts in global production and trade, with
major implications for the role played by emerging economies
and RP firms in GVCs (Cattaneo et al. , 2010; Gereffi, 2014). In
this section, we discuss the key dynamics of GVCs in the post-
crisis global economy from three angles: geographic and value
chain concentration; shifting end markets and regionalization;
and synergistic forms of GVC governance. However, this
analysis should first be related to the growing literature on RPs
and RP firms in IB studies.
Nadvi (2014) has provided a clear and useful operational
definition of "rising powers" that emphasizes six features: rapid
and sustained economic growth; increasing participation in
international trade with dominance in particular sectors;
significant economic scale, including population, natural
resources, a manufacturing base and a sizeable domestic market;
a strong role of the state; local capital (both private and public)
with an expanding international presence; and a growing voice
for civil society. Although these large emerging economies (the
term we will use in this article) were initially associated with
the BRICs (Brazil, Russia, India and China), they now include
more than a dozen countries with similar features, including
Mexico, Indonesia, Nigeria and Turkey (the "MINT" countries),
South Africa and others (Sinkovics et al. , 2014b).
While the emerging economies indeed play a central role in
GVC analysis, the more controversial issue is the status of RP
firms. If "rising powers" refer to countries such as China, India,
Brazil, Russia and South Africa, which are on rapid economic
growth and development trajectories, then RP firms can be
thought of as emergent and with a clear strategic intent to
challenge the Western and dominant forms of economic
organization (Sinkovics and Yamin, 2012). A more contentious
issue, however, is whether RP firms are merely emulating or
"catching up" with MNEs from the advanced industrial
economies, or whether they are fundamentally "changing the
rules of the game" in the contemporary global economy
(Sinkovics et al. , 2014b). Within the traditional IB literature,
the paradigm typically used to address this question is John
Dunning's eclectic ownership, location, and internalization
(OLI) model[7] (Luo and Tung, 2007), sometimes supplemented
with insights from the "late comer" perspective introduced by
economic historian Alexander Gerschenkron[8] (Sinkovics et al.
, 2014b).
From a GVC perspective, there are three shortcomings in the
current literature on RP firms. First, the characterization of RP
firms tends to reflect an outmoded view of the global economy
centered on large national markets and asset-seeking MNEs. In
a GVC-oriented world, value creation, value capture and
economic rents occur in more fluid international production
networks, where the ability to shape innovation processes and
labor and environmental outcomes often resides in the
distribution and retail segments of GVCs (Hamilton et al. ,
2011), and not only in the production activities and OLI
advantages of RP manufacturing and resource-based firms. The
varied nature of GVC governance structures is typically absent
in the analysis of RP firms.
Second, the RP literature usually tries to categorize RP firms as
different in kind from MNEs in the earlier set of East Asia's
NIEs, namely, Hong Kong, Taiwan, Singapore and South Korea
(Luo and Tung, 2007, p. 483). While there clearly are key
distinctions between today's emerging economies and the East
Asian NIEs, beginning with economic scale, notable examples
exist where MNEs from the NIEs are tightly integrated into the
economies of rising powers, especially China, and indeed link
them to the global economy in significant ways that have been
directly responsible for the economic dynamism that is one of
the defining features of the RP. Li & Fung, the largest trading
company in the world, is headquartered in Hong Kong but does
most of its sourcing from China[9]. Similarly, Foxconn
Technology Group, the largest electronics contract manufacturer
in the world, has its home office in Taiwan, but its production
and exports for leading brand name multinationals like Apple
are concentrated in mainland China, where it employs more than
1 million workers, making it by far the largest private employer
in the country. In terms of GVC dynamics, Li & Fung and
Foxconn act like RP firms, even if their headquarters are
elsewhere[10].
Third, one of the most persuasive arguments for the
transformative potential of RP firms is that they are now
pursuing their own low-cost innovation strategies and trying to
leverage the growing size of the low- and middle-income
segments in emerging economies to seek "gold at the base of the
pyramid" and to win the "fight for the middle" in RP markets,
while advanced country MNEs are engaged in "a race to the top"
(Sinkovics et al. , 2014b, p. 677). This indeed could be a very
profitable upgrading approach, but it is not limited to RP firms.
The business press is full of entrepreneurial initiatives being
launched by innovative companies all around the world and not
just in emerging economies, which are empowered by the use of
the Internet, pervasive digital technologies and crowd-sourced
venture capital to solve basic development problems, like the
Chilean entrepreneur who found a cheap way to give hundreds
of millions of people in the world access to clean drinking water
(Wadhwa, 2013). Furthermore, one of the leading RP firms,
China-based Lenovo Group, the top vendor of personal
computers globally, is anchoring its new PC Plus strategy
(based on moving beyond PCs into smartphones, tablets and
servers) not in the China market, but in North America
(Oleniacz, 2014).
The discussion below of recent GVC trends will further
illustrate these and other points related to emerging economies
and RP firms.
The geographic and organizational concentration of GVCs
Over the past decade, GVCs have become significantly more
concentrated, both geographically and organizationally. Despite
the initial expectation that the global spread and fragmentation
of production activities might lead to greater participation by
less-developed countries and smaller firms in GVCs, recent
evidence in a number of industries, from apparel to
automobiles, electronics and even services, suggests that GVCs
are becoming geographically concentrated in fewer countries,
especially emerging economies with large domestic markets and
robust supplier bases, such as Brazil, China, India and South
Africa (Cattaneo et al. , 2010). The trend has been intensified
by the global recession as GVC lead firms streamlined their
supply chains to focus on a smaller number of large, more
capable suppliers, which are strategically located near dynamic
nodes of GVCs (Gereffi, 2014).
The example of mobile phones is illustrative (Lee and Gereffi,
2013). Until the late 1990s, the entire production of mobile
phones was conducted in advanced economies. The ensuing rise
of global outsourcing has shifted production to developing
countries. The five largest exporters - China, South Korea,
Hong Kong, Vietnam and the USA - commanded 74 per cent of
the world ' s exports in 2012, with China alone representing a
half of them[11] (Lee and Gereffi, 2013). As a result, mobile
phone production today is clustered in several countries in Asia,
notably China, South Korea and Vietnam. Moreover, the key
nodes of mobile phone GVCs are significantly consolidated.
The five leading firms account for more than a half of global
markets in mobile phones (56 per cent), smartphones (60 per
cent), contract manufacturing (75 per cent) and smartphone
operating systems (99 per cent). Two leading firms control a big
portion of each market, such as Apple and Samsung in
smartphones, which gives rise to oligopolistic market
structures[12].
There are several implications of this rising concentration in
GVCs. First, upgrading opportunities are unevenly distributed
among countries and firms, and concentration amplifies the
benefits of inclusion and the disadvantages of exclusion in
GVCs. As a significant proportion of world production and
exports is dominated by a handful of countries, the vast
majority of countries and firms are marginalized with few
linkages to global industries and limited upgrading prospects.
Also, the rise of large RP countries as the prominent locations
for GVC production puts pressure on other countries to cut
costs and squeeze their profits to compete. As a result, the
geography of production - which countries are in or out - is
heavily affected by the decisions of a few global brands and
their key contract manufacturers.
For RP firms, rising geographic and value chain concentration
has increased their influence in GVCs. They clearly benefit
from the concentration of production in emerging economies,
and at the same time, their growing capabilities enable global
lead firms to shift more production to these countries. For
example, East Asian contract manufacturers like Foxconn have
taken advantage of capable supplier bases clustered in China, as
exemplified by its supply chain cities (Gereffi, 2009), and
neighboring East Asian countries. As global lead firms like
Apple and Hewlett-Packard are keen to tap into more capable
suppliers, RP firms are better positioned to serve global firms
and advance their positions in GVCs. The rise of large
consolidated, transnational suppliers in RP economies generates
the expectation that they may check the power of global lead
firms (Appelbaum, 2008).
Actual upgrading outcomes, however, are less straightforward.
Some RP firms are big, capable and transnational, but power
asymmetries in their relationship with their global buyers still
cannot be ignored. For example, Apple's iPods and iPhones are
almost entirely assembled in China by Foxconn and Pegatron,
two of the biggest electronics contract manufacturers. Yet, the
value captured by these global contract manufacturers is
extremely small compared to the gains by Apple and other high-
end component suppliers in Japan, Korea and Germany[13]
(Dedrick et al. , 2011). Thin margins and the fast pace of
production virtually dictated by buyers significantly hamper
their ability to improve labor conditions for workers, even after
a series of worker suicides sparked widespread criticism and
intense scrutiny from the public and the media (Chan et al. ,
2013; Lee and Gereffi, 2013).
The extent to which RP firms can contribute to the upgrading of
smaller, less capable suppliers is limited. There is some
expectation that RP firms can facilitate the transfer of
technology and knowledge to smaller firms in the chain. But the
extent to which RP firms can deliver these results depends on
their abilities and strategies to capture more value in GVCs. For
instance, Foxconn manufactures many parts and components in-
house as a way to compensate for slim margins in its contract
manufacturing business (Balfour and Culpan, 2010); this can
limit, if not completely eliminate, their ability to help the
upgradation of smaller suppliers.
Furthermore, there continue to be questions about the
innovative impact of RP firms. Despite China's push for greater
technological autonomy and indigenous innovation, its high-
tech sectors and export performance are still heavily dependent
on foreign-invested enterprises. Of the top 20 exporting firms
based in China in 2012, only 2 were Chinese-owned: Huawei
and ZTE. Twelve of the top 20 exporters were based in Taiwan
(including 6 companies owned by Foxconn), and 4 were from
South Korea (Grimes and Sun, 2014, p. 66).
Shifting end markets and regionalized value chains
In the post-war world economy, international trade was
premised on the fact that most final products were consumed in
developed economies. Upgrading basically meant serving
buyers from advanced economies. For example, export-oriented
industrialization fuelled rapid economic development in the
NIEs, which oriented their development strategies to the export
of manufactured goods to US and European markets, and
Western lead firms knew best how to cater to consumers in
these markets (Hamilton and Gereffi, 2009).
This conventional flow of international trade, however, began to
change in the mid-1980s due to economic slumps in the global
North and rapidly growing market demand in the NIEs. In 1990,
60 per cent of the world trade was between developed countries
(North-North), 30 per cent was between industrialized and
developing countries (North-South) and 10 per cent was South-
South. By 2020, these three patterns of trade are expected to be
equally split, meaning that the relative weight of North-North
trade will have been cut in half in just 30 years (Lamy, 2013). A
major part of this shift is being driven by the fact that almost 60
per cent of trade in goods is now in intermediate products that
are used as imports in the production process, especially for
exports - the so-called GVC trade (UNCTAD, 2013). While the
import content of exports was 20 per cent in 1990, this
increased to 40 per cent in 2010 and it is expected to be 60 per
cent in 2030 (Lamy, 2013).
The resulting shift of end markets to emerging economies was
exacerbated by the 2008-2009 global recession. It had a major
impact on developed economies, while large RP countries like
China, India and Brazil fared relatively better (Gereffi and
Sturgeon, 2013). As world trade bounced back from the
economic crises, developing economies became the main engine
of the recovery (Staritz et al. , 2011). These emerging
economies, unlike the East Asian NIEs, have much bigger
domestic markets and are rich in natural resources. In 2005-
2010, the merchandise imports of the European Union and the
USA increased only by 27 and 14 per cent, respectively, while
emerging economies expanded their merchandise imports much
faster: Brazil (147 per cent), India (129 per cent), China (111
per cent) and South Africa (51 per cent) (WTO, 2011). The
import growth in emerging economies is also driven by rising
demand for intermediate goods and raw materials because
manufacturing GVCs are concentrated in those economies, as
discussed above (Kaplinsky et al. , 2011).
The economic downturn in advanced industrial countries and the
rise of large emerging economies has fueled the regionalization
of value chains. Regional production networks emerged as
factories and suppliers linked through GVCs were clustered into
a reduced number of strategically located countries. A notable
example is the East Asian regional production network. Strong
supply bases, different levels of industrial capabilities and
complementarities between countries for financial,
technological and human resources help the growth of cross-
national production networks in the region. In electronics, for
instance, many high-end components are supplied from Japan,
Korea and Taiwan, which have strong R & D capabilities, and
assembled in China with low-end components produced locally
or in other developing countries, such as Vietnam and the
Philippines (WTO and IDE-JETRO, 2011).
While such regional divisions of labor are not new (Borrus et al.
, 2000; Gereffi, 1996), nowadays more products in diverse
industries are made and consumed regionally instead of being
exported to advanced economies and RP firms play an active
role in creating a regional circuit of production and
consumption. In Sub-Saharan Africa (SSA), South African
supermarkets are building up regional supply chains and
spearheading the diffusion of supermarkets across the region.
So are the supermarkets from Kenya, but on a different
geographic scale. At the same time, the South African, Kenyan
and Ugandan producers have found new markets in the Middle
East and Asia. This provides SSA farmers and producers with
the alternative buyers to global supermarket chains, leading to
the rise of new South-South value chains (Barrientos and
Visser, 2012; Evers et al. , 2014). Similarly, South African
clothing manufacturers recently entered into neighboring
countries like Lesotho and Swaziland to serve mainly South
African and other SSA markets. They work with clients like
South African retailers, who also are expanding regionally
(Morris et al. , 2011).
The regionalization of value chains is also driven by global lead
firms. They tend to focus on a group of countries that are
proximate geographically, economically or socio-linguistically
to promote their localization strategies. Wal-Mart, for example,
has expanded its retail network across SSA with a regional scale
of sourcing, logistics and distribution operations. Similarly,
Vodafone, a UK-based, multinational mobile service provider,
operates across the SSA region to compete against major RP
telecom companies that operate regionally, such as MTN of
South Africa and Bharti Airtel of India. In this way, global
regions have become a locus of competition between local,
regional and global firms, which accelerates the regionalization
of value chains.
The regionalization of value chains can provide RP firms with
some upgrading advantages. First, regional markets and value
chains may present alternative economic upgrading paths where
RP firms may have better chances for functional upgrading than
in global chains (Bazan and Navas-Alemán, 2004; Morris et al. ,
2011). Less stringent standards and lower entry barriers with
less capital and technology requirements in regional value
chains or Southern markets can facilitate smaller firms in
emerging economies to participate in exports and other forms of
business abroad. Second, RP firms can leverage their experience
and knowledge of local and regional markets in the global South
to gain advantages over global firms, which often suffer from a
"liability of outsidership", or a lack of in-depth understanding
of such markets (Johanson and Vahlne, 2009; Sinkovics et al. ,
2014a). For example, the so-called "frugal innovations" (Clark
et al. , 2009) - developing products or services especially
designed for resource-poor settings - may present RP firms with
an opportunity to bypass global firms in serving Southern
consumers, typically with lower incomes and poor services in
power supply and transportation. Such businesses tend to be low
in unit margins, but they can create a high-volume market by
tapping into a large population of new Southern consumers.
However, there are potential downsides for RP firms. The lower
entry barriers of regional or South-South value chains may work
against RP firms if they are stuck in a low-cost, low-standard
market. Furthermore, the advantage of their intimate knowledge
in local markets may not last for long. For example, Chinese
mobile phone makers faced greater competition in the domestic
market as global brands like Nokia and Samsung, after
struggling with localization, caught up fast and closed the gap
with Chinese competitors in terms of understanding local
markets (Brandt and Thun, 2011). Thus, local advantages in
upgrading may be short-lived.
The implications of regionalization for social upgrading are less
clear. Compared to global or North-bound chains, less stringent
social standards in regional value chains and the smaller
premiums Southern consumers may be willing to pay for social
labels could discourage RP firms from committing to an
upgrading of working conditions in their supply chains. Also,
the "high-volume, low-cost" model in Southern markets can
have a negative impact on social upgrading for certain workers
because firms in this model tend to rely on the extensive
outsourcing of "non-core" activities to a large pool of contract
workers whose employment tends to be less stable, as shown in
the case of Indian information technology and telecom firms
(Sarkar et al. , 2013). This may create favorable conditions for
regular, skilled "core" workers, while contract workers suffer
from precarious employment conditions.
From private standards to synergistic governance
As GVCs develop into multi-tier structures where firms in each
tier outsource some of their activities, lead firms use their own
standards to govern the chains and the behavior of the other
chain actors involved. This gives rise to private standards
(Mayer and Gereffi, 2010), which unlike public standards that
are enforced mandatorily by governments, are promulgated and
executed by firms, individually or collectively, and are
voluntary in principle[14]. However, recent studies suggest a
more limited role for lead firms and their private standards in
facilitating upgrading, especially the social dimensions (Locke,
2013; Mayer and Gereffi, 2010), which has led to calls for
synergistic forms of private, public and social governance
(Gereffi et al. , 2014; Mayer, 2014)[15].
There are different types of private standards in GVCs (Ponte
and Gibbon, 2005). Quality standards involve a wide range of
product quality, including product safety. Quality standards,
such as GLOBALGAP (Good Agricultural Practice), have
become critical in GVCs as a number of firms in different
countries affect the quality of final products. Growing demand
for product differentiation among consolidated lead firms
increases the need for private quality standards. Another
expanding area is social and environmental standards (Nadvi,
2014). Global lead firms are increasingly facing public pressure
to make their supply chains socially and environmentally
sustainable. Any corporate wrongdoings in their supply chains
could eventually inflict reputational damage on lead firms even
if the factory is not owned by them.
Private standards have upgrading implications for firms in
developing countries (Humphrey, 2006; Lee et al. , 2012).
Complying with standards requires commitments to various
activities, from additional documentation to facility
improvement, which incur added costs to the firms. Thus,
standards can work as entry barriers for smaller suppliers or
producers that tend to have limited resources. In agri-food
chains, for example, large food manufacturers and supermarkets
are increasingly rationalizing their supply chains to work
directly with a smaller number of preferred, mostly large,
suppliers capable of meeting their stringent requirements,
thereby marginalizing smallholders unable to comply the
standards (Maertens and Swinnen, 2009). By contrast, higher
standards can be a catalyst for upgrading. Improving production
techniques and product quality to meet higher requirements
permits participation in high value-added chains. For example,
some smallholders in developing countries have been successful
in niche markets for organic and fair trade-certified products,
differentiating themselves from non-certified producers (van
Beuningen and Knorringa, 2009).
Over the past decade or so, the "compliance-based model"
(Locke et al. , 2009) of governing GVCs through private
standards aimed at improving quality, social and environmental
outcomes has proven inadequate to address these concerns. With
regard to labor conditions, the ineffectiveness of the compliance
model has been under intense scrutiny following a series of
highly publicized tragic events. Dozens of worker suicides in
Foxconn's factories in China since 2010 shed light on horrific
conditions that confront those who assembled high-tech
products like the iPhone. The latest building collapse in
Bangladesh that killed over a thousand garment workers in 2013
illuminates the precarious factory conditions under which
garments are manufactured by suppliers for global retail and
apparel brands like H & M, Zara and Tesco. In many of such
cases, contributing to these undesirable conditions are the
buyers' own purchasing and supply chain management practices,
such as cost-cutting, shortening lead times and last-minute
changes, which often make the supplier unable to observe their
labor codes (Barrientos, 2013).
The limited impact of the compliance model has led to a search
for alternative paths for social upgrading (Gereffi and Luo,
2014). More attention is being given to joint actions by multiple
stakeholders to combine compliance monitoring with capability
building so that supplier can learn how to address labor issues
on their own (O'Rourke, 2006). Moreover, bottom-up
approaches highlight the importance of local embeddedness.
While developing country firms tend to be portrayed as
"standard-takers", they can initiate their own effort to improve
working conditions, often collectively within clusters (Lund-
Thomsen and Nadvi, 2010). Active roles can be played by
workers and labor unions in GVCs, who often are the best
monitors on the ground (O'Rourke, 2006) and who have
considerable power to disrupt the supply chains in their
bargaining with employers (Selwyn, 2013).
Finally, in the face of workers' grievances and public criticisms
over undesirable labor conditions, governments need to enforce
stricter labor laws and regulations and actively police labor
abuses. Government actions can go beyond the traditional law-
enforcing role and adopt innovative and experimental
approaches by collaborating with private and civil actors
(Locke, 2013). Different forms of governance can work together
to complement each other (Amengual, 2010), and this can lead
to "synergistic governance" (Mayer, 2014). To make this
happen, one needs to go beyond the factory as the unit of
analysis (and intervention) to take into account a broader array
of governance forms and public and civil society actors that
could complement private GVC governance and global lead
firms (Gereffi et al. , 2014).
Conclusion
Our discussion of the changing dynamics of GVCs in the post-
crisis global economy underscores the important yet complex
role of GVCs in shaping economic and social outcomes for RP
firms and emerging economies. Rising geographic and
organizational concentration in many GVCs leads to an uneven
distribution of upgrading opportunities that should favor RP
firms. Similarly, the rise of emerging economies as new end
markets for GVCs and the regionalization of value chains can
benefit RP firms. RP firms can play a significant role in
reconstructing GVCs by building up regional supply chains and
retail networks and South-South value chains. These can
provide alternative markets where RP firms complete with
global firms on better terms, either with more local knowledge
or business models uniquely suited to developing country
markets. At the same time, without further upgrading, such
competitive advantage may be short-lived or only sustainable at
the expense of worsening labor conditions for marginalized
workers.
However, this article has also challenged some of the current
stereotypes about RP firms. They need to be analyzed within the
context of contemporary GVCs, not just as the newest variety of
"third world multinationals". MNEs from the East Asian NIEs
have had a strong influence not only on the export performance
of emerging economies, particularly China, but also on their
innovation potential. As RP firms become fully integrated into
GVCs, their global strategies can be powerfully influenced by
their linkages to advanced countries as well as their domestic
markets[16].
In terms of new patterns of GVC governance focused on social
upgrading, the inability of voluntary corporate codes to address
the root causes of poor labor conditions in the factories linked
to GVCs has led to the call for joint governance systems built
through a cooperation of MNEs, local firms and transnational
and local NGOs, labor unions and governments on various
levels. It remains to be seen whether such cooperative
governance can address a wider array of social development
issues beyond workplace and workers' rights. Thus, the
conditions under which social value and benefits are likely to be
co-created within and across private, public or civil sector
(Sinkovics et al. , 2014a) can be one of the topics on which
GVC and critical IB scholars can fruitfully collaborate. In such
an endeavor, critical IB scholarship could contribute to the
GVC approach by providing a deep understanding of MNEs'
hierarchical governance, various business strategies beyond
supply chain management and internal decision-making and
coordination process across different geographies.
Corresponding author
Joonkoo Lee can be contacted at: [email protected]
Notes
Global production network (GPN) research has many
commonalities with the GVC approach, as both pay close
attention to fragmented and dispersed production systems across
national borders. Efforts to distinguish the two perspectives
highlight the former's relative emphasis on local institutions and
embeddedness (Coe et al. , 2008; Henderson et al. , 2002; Hess
and Yeung, 2006), while GVC analysis deals more specifically
with vertical commercial linkages and the role of power in
global supply chains (Bair, 2009; Ponte and Sturgeon, 2014).
This paper, however, focuses on the GVC literature to highlight
its potential contribution to the critical IB literature. For a
comparison of the GPN and GVC literatures, see Sturgeon
(2001, 2009) and Neilson et al. (2014).
By 2011, Nike's products were made in 930 factories in 50
countries, employing more than 1 million workers. However,
Nike itself had just 38,000 direct employees, most of whom
work in the USA. Nike's $15 billion in total sales included
$10.3 billion for footwear and $5 billion for apparel. However,
just 73 of Nike's 930 suppliers in 2011 were producing shoes,
and most were located in Asia (Locke, 2013, p. 48). This
highlights the fact that similar industries in terms of products
often have contrasting forms of industrial organization, GVC
governance structures and upgrading outcomes, even with the
same lead firm. This is true of Nike's buyer-driven footwear and
apparel suppliers: offshore footwear factories are relatively
large, capital-intensive operations, which Nike was able to
monitor much more closely, while garment factories are usually
smaller and highly labor-intensive operations, leading to much
greater volatility in performance and compliance with Nike's
corporate codes of conduct.
The biggest car part suppliers (with 2013 revenues in
parentheses) include Bosch ($67.5 billion, 2012); Continental
($44.3 billion); Denso ($43.3 billion); Johnson Controls ($42.7
billion) and Magna International ($34.8 billion). Some of the
leading car companies they supply include Honda Motor
($119.5 billion), Fiat ($115.3 billion) and BMW ($101 billion)
(Foy, 2014). The global top 10 auto parts suppliers account for
60 per cent of total revenues of the world's 100 largest
automotive suppliers.
Operating margins of the ten largest automotive suppliers are
about 4 percentage points higher, on average, than those of the
ten biggest carmakers (Foy, 2014).
The role of mega suppliers in the automotive value chain is
paralleled by the rise of global contract manufacturers in
electronics (Sturgeon and Lester, 2004), and large-scale systems
integrators in the aircraft and shipbuilding industries (Gereffi et
al. , 2013).
"Capturing the Gains" is an international research network to
examine the relationship between economic and social
upgrading in GVCs. The project publications, working papers,
policy briefs and other activities are listed at
www.capturingthegains.org/
The three main components of the OLI eclectic paradigm are:
ownership advantages, locational advantages and internalization
advantages.
For an updated version of the "late comer" thesis applied to
developmental states in East Asia and elsewhere, see the
discussion of "compressed development" in Whittaker et al.
(2010).
Li & Fung has about 15,000 suppliers globally and operates in
more than 40 countries (Fung, 2011).
A similar argument could be made with respect to the dynamics
of "triangle manufacturing" whereby MNEs from the East Asian
NIEs played a critical role in extending production in GVCs to a
broad range of low-cost locations that included small countries
as well as RP economies, thereby creating more flexible
sourcing networks that leveraged quota and regional trade
agreement constraints and preferences in ways that increased
participation by low-income economies, including RPs, in
GVCs (Gereffi, 1999). This is perhaps most clearly visible in
the global apparel industry; see Morris et al. (2011) on South
Africa's links to Lesotho and Swaziland and Bair and Gereffi
(2014) on how East Asian production networks in Nicaragua are
leveraging features of the Central America Free Trade
Agreement (CAFTA) and North American Free Trade
Agreement (NAFTA) trade agreements.
Similarly, over 40 per cent of the world's apparel exports came
from China alone, and the top 5 leading exporting countries
accounted for 60 per cent of world export value in 2010
(Bernhardt, 2013).
Figures on mobile phone sales (2012) and smartphone OS
(2012, 4Q) are from Gartner (2013b). Smartphone sales figures
(2013, 2Q) are from Gartner (2013a). Market shares in contract
manufacturing (2010) are from NIPA (2011).
US-based Apple is estimated to capture between one-third and
one-half of an iPod's retail price; Asian firms, like Toshiba
from Japan and Samsung from South Korea, capture the largest
manufacturing shares as profits from high-value components,
such as the hard-disk drive, display and memory; and the
assembly and testing activities by Chinese workers get just 2
per cent of the final product price (Timmer et al. , 2014, p. 99).
Private standards can be mandatory in a de facto sense if
complying with them is a precondition for participation in the
GVC.
Public governance involves rules and regulations set by various
levels of governments in nation-states and supra-national
entities like the International Labor Organization. Social
governance is driven by civil society actors such as non-
governmental organizations (NGOs) and labor unions. It
includes codes of conduct initiated by NGOs and multi-
stakeholder initiatives, such as Ethical Trade Initiative.
This is the case of India's role in the dynamic offshore services
GVC, which began with "body shopping" in the US. economy in
the late 1990s in response to the perceived need to rewrite
massive amounts of software code to avert a potential Y2K
crisis, and has evolved to the point where India has some of the
world's leading offshore services MNEs, such as Infosys, Wipro
and Tata Consultancy Services, but still oriented to global
clients (Fernandez-Stark et al. , 2011).
References
References
Amengual, M. ( 2010 ), " Complementary labor regulation: the
uncoordinated combination of state and private regulators in the
Dominican Republic ",World Development , Vol. 38 No. 3, pp.
405 - 414 .
Appelbaum, R.P. ( 2008 ), " Giant transnational contractors in
East Asia: emergent trends in global supply chains
",Competition & Change , Vol. 12 No. 1, pp. 69 - 87 .
Bair, J. ( 2005 ), " Global capitalism and commodity chains:
looking back, going forward ",Competition & Change , Vol. 9
No. 2, pp. 153 - 180 .
Bair, J. ( 2009 ), " Global commodity chains: genealogy and
review ", in Bair, J. (Ed.),Frontiers of Commodity Chain
Research , Stanford University Press, Stanford, CA, pp. 1 - 34 .
Bair, J. and Gereffi, G. ( 2001 ), " Local clusters in global
chains: the causes and consequences of export dynamism in
Torreon's blue jeans industry ",World Development , Vol. 29
No. 11, pp. 1885 - 1903 .
Bair, J. and Gereffi, G. ( 2014 ), " Towards better work in
Central America: Nicaragua and the CAFTA Context ", in
Rossi, A., Luinstra, A. and Pickles, J. (Eds),Towards Better
Work: Understanding Labour in Apparel Global Value Chains ,
Palgrave Macmillan, Houndmills, pp. 251 - 275 .
Balfour, F. and Culpan, T. ( 2010 ), " The man who makes your
iPhone ", available at:
www.businessweek.com/magazine/content/10_38/b41950584234
79.htm
Barrientos, S. ( 2013 ), " Corporate purchasing practices in
global production networks: a socially contested terrain
",Geoforum , Vol. 44, pp. 44 - 51 .
Barrientos, S., Gereffi, G. and Nathan, D. ( 2012 ), " Economic
and social upgrading in global value chains: emerging trends
and pressures ", Capturing the Gains Summit Briefing,
University of Manchester, available at:
www.capturingthegains.org/pdf/CTG-GVC.pdf
Barrientos, S., Gereffi, G. and Rossi, A. ( 2011 ), " Economic
and social upgrading in global production networks: a new
paradigm for a changing world ",International Labour Review ,
Vol. 150 Nos 3/4, pp. 319 - 340 .
Barrientos, S. and Visser, M. ( 2012 ), " South African
horticulture: opportunities and challenges for economic and
social upgrading in value chains ", Capturing the Gains
Working Paper 2012/12, University of Manchester, available at:
www.capturingthegains.org/publications/workingpapers/wp_201
212.htm
Bazan, L. and Navas-Alemán, L. ( 2004 ), " The underground
revolution in the Sinos Valley: a comparison of upgrading in
global and national value chains ", in Schmitz, H. (Ed.),Local
Enterprises in the Global Economy: Issues of Governance and
Upgrading , Elgar, Cheltenham, pp. 110 - 139 .
Bernhardt, T. ( 2013 ), " Developing countries in the global
apparel value chain: a tale of upgrading and downgrading
experiences ", Capturing the Gains Working Paper 2013/22,
available at:
www.capturingthegains.org/publications/workingpapers/wp_201
322.htm
Borrus, M.G., Ernst, D. and Haggard, S. ( 2000 ),International
Production Networks in Asia: Rivalry or Riches? Routledge,
London .
Brandt, L. and Thun, E. ( 2011 ), " Going mobile in China:
shifting value chains and upgrading in the mobile telecom
sector ",International Journal of Technological Learning,
Innovation and Development , Vol. 4 Nos 1/3, pp. 148 - 180 .
Buckley, P.J. ( 2009 ), " The impact of the global factory on
economic development ",Journal of World Business , Vol. 44
No. 2, pp. 131 - 143 .
Buckley, P.J. and Ghauri, P.N. ( 2004 ), " Globalisation,
economic geography and the strategy of multinational
enterprises ",Journal of International Business Studies , Vol. 35
No. 2, pp. 81 - 98 .
Cattaneo, O., Gereffi, G. and Staritz, C. ( 2010 ),Global Value
Chains in a Postcrisis World: A Development Perspective ,
World Bank, Washington, DC .
Chan, J., Pun, N. and Selden, M. ( 2013 ), " The politics of
global production: Apple, Foxconn and China's new working
class ",New Technology, Work and Employment , Vol. 28 No.
2, pp. 100 - 115 .
Clark, N., Chataway, J., Hanlin, R., Kale, D., Kaplinsky, R.,
Muraguri, L., Papaioannou, T., Robbins, P. and Wamae, W. (
2009 ), " Below the radar: what does innovation in the Asian
driver economies have to offer other low income economies ",
Innogen Working Paper No. 69, Milton Keynes, available at:
http://oro.open.ac.uk/15241 /
Coe, N.M., Dicken, P. and Hess, M. ( 2008 ), " Global
production networks: realizing the potential ",Journal of
Economic Geography , Vol. 8 No. 3, pp. 271 - 295 .
De Marchi, V., Di Maria, E. and Ponte, S. ( 2014 ), "
Multinational firms and the management of global networks:
insights from global value chain studies ", in Pedersen, T.,
Venzin, M., Devinney, T.M. and Tihanyi, L. (Eds),Orchestration
of the Global Network Organization (Advances in International
Management) , Emerald, Bingley, Vol. 27, pp. 463 - 486 .
Dedrick, J., Kraemer, K.L. and Linden, G. ( 2011 ), " The
distribution of value in the mobile phone supply chain
",Telecommunications Policy , Vol. 35 No. 6, pp. 505 - 521 .
Donaghu, M.T. and Barff, R. ( 1990 ), " Nike just did it:
international subcontracting and flexibility in athletic footwear
production ",Regional Studies , Vol. 24 No. 6, pp. 537 - 552 .
Evers, B., Opondo, M., Barrientos, S., Krishnan, A., Amoding,
F. and Ndlovu, L. ( 2014 ), " Global and regional supermarkets:
implications for producers and workers in Kenyan and Ugandan
horticulture ", Capturing the Gains Working Paper 2014/39,
available at:
www.capturingthegains.org/publications/workingpapers/wp_201
212.htm
Farole, T. and Winkler, D. ( 2014 ),Making Foreign Direct
Investment Work for Sub-Saharan Africa: Local Spillovers and
Competitiveness in Global Value Chains , World Bank
Publications, Washington, DC .
Fernandez-Stark, K., Bamber, P. and Gereffi, G. ( 2011 ), " The
offshore services value chain: upgrading trajectories in
developing countries ",International Journal of Technological
Learning, Innovation and Development , Vol. 4 Nos 1/3, pp. 206
- 234 .
Fold, N. ( 2002 ), " Lead firms and competition in 'bi-polar'
commodity chains: grinders and branders in the global cocoa-
chocolate industry ",Journal of Agrarian Change , Vol. 2 No. 2,
pp. 228 - 247 .
Foy, H. ( 2014 ), " Age of mega supplier heralds danger for
carmakers ",Financial Times , available at:
www.ft.com/intl/cms/s/0/50c272c4-dce9-11e3-ba13-
00144feabdc0.html #slide0
Fung, V. ( 2011 ), " Global supply chains - past developments,
emerging trends ", available at:
www.fungglobalinstitute.org/en/global-supply-chains-
%E2%80%93-past-developments-emerging-trends
Gartner . ( 2013a ), " Gartner says smartphone sales grew 46.5
per cent in second quarter of 2013 and exceeded feature phone
sales for first time ", available at:
www.gartner.com/newsroom/id/2573415
Gartner . ( 2013b ), " Gartner says worldwide mobile phone
sales declined 1.7 per cent in 2012 ", available at:
www.gartner.com/newsroom/id/2335616
Gereffi, G. ( 1994 ), " The organization of buyer-driven global
commodity chains: how US retailers shape overseas production
networks ", in Gereffi, G. and Korzeniewicz, M.
(Eds),Commodity Chains and Global Capitalism , Greenwood
Press, Westport, CT, pp. 95 - 122 .
Gereffi, G. ( 1996 ), " Commodity chains and regional divisions
of labor in East Asia ",Journal of Asian Business , Vol. 12 No.
1, pp. 75 - 112 .
Gereffi, G. ( 1999 ), " International trade and industrial
upgrading in the apparel commodity chains ",Journal of
International Economics , Vol. 48 No. 1, pp. 37 - 70 .
Gereffi, G. ( 2009 ), " Development models and industrial
upgrading in China and Mexico ",European Sociological Review
, Vol. 25 No. 1, pp. 37 - 51 .
Gereffi, G. ( 2014 ), " Global value chains in a post-Washington
Consensus world ",Review of International Political Economy ,
Vol. 21 No. 1, pp. 9 - 37 .
Gereffi, G., Brun, L., Stokes, S. and Guinn, A. ( 2013 ), " The
NSPS shipbuilding value chain ", available at:
www.cggc.duke.edu/pdfs/NSPS_GVC_Analysis_Jan2013_01282
013.pdf
Gereffi, G. and Fernandez-Stark, K. ( 2011 ), " Global value
chain analysis: a primer ", Center on Globalization, Governance
& Competitiveness, Durham, NC, available at:
www.cggc.duke.edu/pdfs/2011-05-
31_GVC_analysis_a_primer.pdf
Gereffi, G. and Kaplinsky, R. ( 2001 ),The Value of Value
Chains: Spreading the Gains from Globalisation , Institute of
Development Studies, Brighton .
Gereffi, G. and Korzeniewicz, M. ( 1994 ),Commodity Chains
and Global Capitalism , Greenwood Press, Westport, CT .
Gereffi, G. and Lee, J. ( 2012 ), " Why the world suddenly cares
about global supply chains ",Journal of Supply Chain
Management , Vol. 48 No. 3, pp. 24 - 32 .
Gereffi, G. and Luo, X. ( 2014 ), " Risks and opportunities of
participation in global value chains ", Policy Research Working
Paper 6847, World Bank, Washington, DC .
Gereffi, G., Regini, M. and Sabel, C.F. ( 2014 ), " On Richard
M. Locke, the promise and limits of private power: promoting
labor standards in a global economy, New York, Cambridge
University Press, 2013 ",Socio-Economic Review , Vol. 12 No.
1, pp. 219 - 235 .
Gereffi, G. and Sturgeon, T.J. ( 2013 ), " Global value chain-
oriented industrial policy: the role of emerging economies ", in
Elms, D.K. and Low, P. (Eds),Global Value Chains in a
Changing World , World Trade Organization, Fung Global
Institute and Temasek Foundation Centre for Trade &
Negotiations, Geneva, pp. 329 - 360 .
Gereffi, G., Humphrey, J. and Sturgeon, T. ( 2005 ), " The
governance of global value chains ",Review of International
Political Economy , Vol. 12 No. 1, pp. 78 - 104 .
Ghauri, P.N. and Yamin, M. ( 2009 ), " Revisiting the impact of
multinational enterprises on economic development ",Journal of
World Business , Vol. 44 No. 2, pp. 105 - 107 .
Gibbon, P. and Ponte, S. ( 2008 ), " Global value chains: from
governance to governmentality? ",Economy and Society , Vol.
37 No. 3, pp. 365 - 392 .
Gifford, B., Kestler, A. and Anand, S. ( 2010 ), " Building local
legitimacy into corporate social responsibility: gold mining
firms in developing nations ",Journal of World Business , Vol.
45 No. 3, pp. 304 - 311 .
Giuliani, E., Pietrobelli, C. and Rabellotti, R. ( 2005 ), "
Upgrading in global value chains: lessons from Latin American
clusters ",World Development , Vol. 33 No. 4, pp. 549 - 573 .
Grimes, S. and Sun, Y. ( 2014 ), " Implications of China's on-
going dependence on foreign technology ",Geoforum , Vol. 54,
pp. 59 - 69 .
Hamilton, G.G. and Gereffi, G. ( 2009 ), " Global commodity
chains, market makers, and the rise of demand-responsive
economies ", in Bair, J. (Ed.),Frontiers of Commodity Chain
Research , Stanford University Press, Stanford, CA, pp. 136 -
161 .
Hamilton, G.G., Senauer, B. and Petrovic, M. ( 2011 ),The
Market Makers: How Retailers Are Reshaping the Global
Economy , Oxford University Press, Oxford, New York, NY .
Henderson, J., Dicken, P., Hess, M., Coe, N. and Yeung,
H.W.C. ( 2002 ), " Global production networks and the analysis
of economic development ",Review of International Political
Economy , Vol. 9 No. 3, pp. 436 - 464 .
Hess, M. and Yeung, H.W.-C. ( 2006 ), " Whither global
production networks in economic geography? Past, present, and
future ",Environment and Planning A , Vol. 38 No. 7, pp. 1193 -
1204 .
Humphrey, J. ( 2006 ), " Policy implications of trends in
agribusiness value chains ",European Journal of Development
Research , Vol. 18 No. 4, pp. 572 - 592 .
Humphrey, J. and Schmitz, H. ( 2002 ), " How does insertion in
global value chains affect upgrading in industrial clusters?
",Regional Studies , Vol. 36 No. 9, pp. 1017 - 1027 .
Islam, M.S. ( 2008 ), " From pond to plate: towards a twin-
driven commodity chain in Bangladesh shrimp aquaculture
",Food Policy , Vol. 33 No. 3, pp. 209 - 223 .
Jiang, X. and Milberg, W. ( 2013 ), " Capturing the jobs from
globalisation: trade and employment in global value chains ",
Capturing the Gains Working Paper 2013/30, University of
Manchester, available at:
www.capturingthegains.org/publications/workingpapers/wp_201
330.htm
Johanson, J. and Vahlne, J.E. ( 2009 ), " The Uppsala
internationalization process model revisited: from liability of
foreignness to liability of outsidership ",Journal of International
Business Studies , Vol. 40 No. 9, pp. 1411 - 1431 .
Kaplinsky, R., Terheggen, A. and Tijaja, J. ( 2011 ), " China as
a final market: the Gabon timber and Thai cassava value chains
",World Development , Vol. 39 No. 7, pp. 1177 - 1190 .
Kawakami, M. ( 2011 ), " Inter-firm dynamics of notebook PC
value chains and the rise of Taiwanese original design
manufacturing firms ", in Kawakami, M. and Sturgeon, T.
(Eds),The Dynamics of Local Learning in Global Value Chains:
Experiences from East Asia , Palgrave Macmillan, Basingstoke,
pp. 16 - 42 .
Lamy, P. ( 2013 ), " Global value chains, interdependence, and
the future of trade ", available at:
www.voxeu.org/article/global-value-chains-interdependence-
and-future-trade
Lee, J. ( 2010 ), " Global commodity chains and global value
chains ", in Denemark, R.A. (Ed.),The International Studies
Encyclopedia , Wiley-Blackwell, Oxford, pp. 2987 - 3006 .
Lee, J.R. and Chen, J.S. ( 2000 ), " Dynamic synergy creation
with multiple business activities: toward a competence-based
growth model for contract manufacturers ",Advances in Applied
Business Strategy , Vol. 6A, pp. 209 - 228 .
Lee, J. and Gereffi, G. ( 2013 ), " The co-evolution of
concentration in mobile phone global value chains and its
impact on social upgrading in developing countries ", Capturing
the Gains Working Paper 2013/25, available at:
www.capturingthegains.org/publications/workingpapers/wp_201
325.htm
Lee, J., Gereffi, G. and Barrientos, S. ( 2011 ), " Global value
chains, upgrading and poverty reduction ", Capturing the Gains
Briefing Note No. 3, available at:
www.capturingthegains.org/pdf/ctg_briefing_note_3.pdf
Lee, J., Gereffi, G. and Beauvais, J. ( 2012 ), " Global value
chains and agrifood standards: challenges and possibilities for
smallholders in developing countries ",Proceedings of the
National Academy of Sciences of the United States of America ,
Vol. 191 No. 31, pp. 12326 - 12331 .
Locke, R.M. ( 2013 ),The Promise and Limits of Private Power:
Promoting Labor Standards in a Global Economy , Cambridge
University Press, Cambridge, NY .
Locke, R., Amengual, M. and Mangla, A. ( 2009 ), " Virtue out
of necessity? Compliance, commitment, and the improvement of
labor conditions in global supply chains ",Politics & Society ,
Vol. 37 No. 3, pp. 319 - 351 .
Lund-Thomsen, P. and Nadvi, K. ( 2010 ), " Clusters, chains
and compliance: corporate social responsibility and governance
in football manufacturing in South Asia ",Journal of Business
Ethics , Vol. 93 No. 2, pp. 201 - 222 .
Luo, Y. and Tung, R.L. ( 2007 ), " International expansion of
emerging market enterprises: a springboard perspective
",Journal of International Business Studies , Vol. 38 No. 4, pp.
481 - 498 .
Maertens, M. and Swinnen, J.F.M. ( 2009 ), " Trade, standards,
and poverty: evidence from Senegal ",World Development ,
Vol. 37 No. 1, pp. 161 - 178 .
Mayer, F. ( 2014 ), " Leveraging private governance for public
purpose: business, civil society and the state in labour
regulation ", in Payne, A. and Philips, N. (Eds),Handbook on
the International Political Economy of Governance , Edward
Elgar, Cheltenham, pp. 344 - 360 .
Mayer, F. and Gereffi, G. ( 2010 ), " Regulation and economic
globalization: prospects and limits of private governance
",Business and Politics , Vol. 12 No. 3 .
Meyer, K.E. ( 2004 ), " Perspectives on multinational
enterprises in emerging economies ",Journal of International
Business Studies , Vol. 35 No. 4, pp. 259 - 276 .
Morris, M., Staritz, C. and Barnes, J. ( 2011 ), " Value chain
dynamics, local embeddedness, and upgrading in the clothing
sectors of Lesotho and Swaziland ",International Journal of
Technological Learning, Innovation and Development , Vol. 4
Nos 1/3, pp. 96 - 119 .
Nadvi, K. ( 2014 ), " 'Rising powers' and labour and
environmental standards ",Oxford Development Studies , Vol.
42 No. 2, pp. 137 - 150 .
Neilson, J., Pritchard, B. and Yeung, H.W.C. ( 2014 ), " Global
value chains and global production networks in the changing
international political economy: an introduction ",Review of
International Political Economy , Vol. 21 No. 1, pp. 1 - 8 .
NIPA ( 2011 ),The Rise of EMS/ODM Industry and Its
Implications , National IT Industry Promotion Agency, Seoul .
Oetzel, J. and Doh, J.P. ( 2009 ), " MNEs and development: a
review and reconceptualization ",Journal of World Business ,
Vol. 44 No. 2, pp. 108 - 120 .
Oleniacz, L. ( 2014 ), " Lenovo North America president: PC
Plus strategy is paying off ",Durham Morning Herald .
O'Rourke, D. ( 2006 ), " Multi-stakeholder regulation:
privatizing or socializing global labor standards? ",World
Development , Vol. 34 No. 5, pp. 899 - 918 .
Ponte, S. and Gibbon, P. ( 2005 ), " Quality standards,
conventions and the governance of global value chains
",Economy and Society , Vol. 34 No. 1, pp. 1 - 31 .
Ponte, S. and Sturgeon, T. ( 2014 ), " Explaining governance in
global value chains: a modular theory-building effort ",Review
of International Political Economy , Vol. 21 No. 1, pp. 195 -
223 .
Sarkar, S., Mehta, B.S. and Nathan, D. ( 2013 ), " How social
upgrading drives economic upgrading by Indian IT majors: the
case of telecom IT services ", Capturing the Gains Working
Paper 2013/27, University of Manchester, available at:
www.capturingthegains.org/publications/workingpapers/wp_201
327.htm
Schmitz, H. ( 2004 ),Local Enterprises in the Global Economy:
Issues of Governance and Upgrading , Edward Elgar,
Cheltenham .
Selwyn, B. ( 2013 ), " Social upgrading and labour in global
production networks: a critique and an alternative conception
",Competition & Change , Vol. 17 No. 1, pp. 75 - 90 .
Sinkovics, N., Sinkovics, R.R. and Yamin, M. ( 2014a ), " The
role of social value creation in business model formulation at
the bottom of the pyramid - implications for MNEs?
",International Business Review , Vol. 23 No. 4, pp. 692 - 707 .
Sinkovics, R.R. and Yamin, M. ( 2012 ), " Special issue on
rising power firms and FDI: the challenge of economic
development ",Critical Perspectives on International Business ,
Vol. 8 No. 4 .
Sinkovics, R.R., Yamin, M., Nadvi, K. and Zhang, Y.Z. ( 2014b
), " Rising powers from emerging markets - the changing face of
international business ",International Business Review , Vol. 23
No. 4, pp. 675 - 679 .
Staritz, C., Gereffi, G. and Cattaneo, O. ( 2011 ), " Editorial
",International Journal of Technological Learning, Innovation
and Development , Vol. 4 Nos 1/3, pp. 1 - 12 .
Sturgeon, T.J. ( 2001 ), " How do we define value chains and
production networks? ",IDS Bulletin , Vol. 32 No. 3, pp. 9 - 18 .
Sturgeon, T.J. ( 2009 ), " From commodity chains to value
chains: interdisciplinary theory building in an age of
globalization ", in Bair, J. (Ed.),Frontiers of Commodity Chain
Research , Stanford University Press, Stanford, CA, pp. 110 -
135 .
Sturgeon, T.J. and Lester, R.K. ( 2004 ), " The new global
supply-base: new challenges for local suppliers in East Asia ",
in Yusuf, S., Altaf, M.A. and Nabeshima, K. (Eds),Global
Production Networking and Technological Change in East Asia ,
Oxford University Press, Oxford, pp. 35 - 87 .
Timmer, M.P., Erumban, A.A., Los, B., Stehrer, R. and de
Vries, G.J. ( 2014 ), " Slicing up global value chains ",Journal
of Economic Perspectives , Vol. 28 No. 2, pp. 99 - 118 .
UNCTAD ( 2013 ), " Global value chains and development:
investment and value added trade in the global economy ",
United Nations Conference on Trade and Development, Geneva,
available at:
http://unctad.org/en/publicationslibrary/diae2013d1_en.pdf
van Beuningen, C. and Knorringa, P. ( 2009 ),Inclusive
Improvement: Standards and Smallholders - Taking Stock and
Moving On , Hivos, The Hague .
Wadhwa, V. ( 2013 ), " A lesson from Chile ",Wall Street
Journal , available at:
http://blogs.wsj.com/accelerators/2013/08/26/vivek-wadhwa-a-
lesson-from-chile /
Whittaker, D., Zhu, T., Sturgeon, T., Tsai, M. and Okita, T. (
2010 ), " Compressed development ",Studies in Comparative
International Development , Vol. 45 No. 4, pp. 439 - 467 .
Williamson, O. ( 1985 ),The Economic Institutions of
Capitalism: Firms, Markets, Relational Contracting , Free Press,
New York, NY .
WTO ( 2011 ),International Trade Statistics 2011 , World Trade
Organization, Geneva .
WTO and IDE-JETRO ( 2011 ), " Trade patterns and global
value chains in East Asia: from trade in goods to trade in tasks
", World Trade Organization and Institute of Developing
Economies, Geneva and Tokyo, available at:
www.wto.org/english/res_e/publications_e/stat_tradepat_globva
lchains_e.htm
Yamin, M. and Sinkovics, R.R. ( 2009 ), " Infrastructure or
foreign direct investment? An examination of the implications
of MNE strategy for economic development ",Journal of World
Business , Vol. 44 No. 2, pp. 144 - 157 .
AuthorAffiliation
Joonkoo Lee School of Business, Hanyang University, Seoul,
South Korea
Gary Gereffi Department of Sociology, Duke University,
Durham, North Carolina, USA
Word count: 11271
Show less
You have requested "on-the-fly" machine translation of selected
content from our databases. This functionality is provided
solely for your convenience and is in no way intended to replace
human translation. Show full disclaimer
Neither ProQuest nor its licensors make any representations or
warranties with respect to the translations. The translations are
automatically generated "AS IS" and "AS AVAILABLE" and
are not retained in our systems. PROQUEST AND ITS
LICENSORS SPECIFICALLY DISCLAIM ANY AND ALL
EXPRESS OR IMPLIED WARRANTIES, INCLUDING
WITHOUT LIMITATION, ANY WARRANTIES FOR
AVAILABILITY, ACCURACY, TIMELINESS,
COMPLETENESS, NON-INFRINGMENT,
MERCHANTABILITY OR FITNESS FOR A PARTICULAR
PURPOSE. Your use of the translations is subject to all use
restrictions contained in your Electronic Products License
Agreement and by using the translation functionality you agree
to forgo any and all claims against ProQuest or its licensors for
your use of the translation functionality and any output derived
there from. Hide full disclaimer Translations powered by LEC.
Translations powered by LEC.
© Emerald Group Publishing Limited 2015
English
Arabic
BRQ Business Research Quarterly (2017) 20, 137---150
www.elsevier.es/brq
BRQBusiness ResearchQuarterly
REVIEW ESSAY
Global value chain configuration: A review and
research agenda
Virginia Hernándeza,∗ , Torben Pedersenb
a University Carlos III of Madrid, Business Management
Division, C/ Madrid, 126, 28903 Getafe, Madrid, Spain
b Bocconi University, Department of Management and
Technology, Via Roentgen 1, 20136 Milan, Italy
Received 28 November 2015; accepted 29 November 2016
Available online 23 January 2017
JEL
CLASSIFICATION
M16
KEYWORDS
Literature review;
Global value chain;
International
business;
GVC configuration
Abstract This paper reviews the literature on global value
chain configuration, providing an
overview of this topic. Specifically, we review the
literature focusing on the concept of the
global value chain and its activities, the decisions involved
in its configuration, such as location,
the governance modes chosen and the different ways of
coordinating them. We also examine
the outcomes of a global value chain configuration in
terms of performance and upgrading. Our
aim is to review the state of the art of these issues,
identify research gaps and suggest new
lines for future research that would advance our
understanding of how firms are implementing
new ways of organizing and managing activities on a
global scale.
© 2016 ACEDE. Published by Elsevier España, S.L.U. This
is an open access article under the CC
BY-NC-ND license (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by-
nc-nd/4.0/).
Introduction
A vast amount of research has focused on different
configu-
rational aspects of firms’ activities worldwide. Specifically,
an important part of the literature has focused on explain-
ing the reasons and effects of locating individual activities
in foreign countries (Lewin et al., 2009; Martínez-Noya
and
García-Canal, 2011; Rodríguez and Nieto, 2016;
Schmeisser,
2013). Nevertheless, research has increasingly broadened
this perspective to go beyond the analysis of specific
∗ Corresponding author.
E-mail addresses: [email protected] (V. Hernández),
[email protected] (T. Pedersen).
activities and encompass the whole value chain. This has
prompted the emergence of several lines of research
examining different aspects of the global value chain
configuration, including: governance types (Buckley and
Strange, 2015; Gereffi et al., 2005), levels of
disaggregation
(Asmussen et al., 2007; Beugelsdijk et al., 2009),
geographic
scope (Los et al., 2015; Mudambi and Puck, 2016), and
the
upgrading processes of the firms involved (De Marchi et
al.,
2013; Humphrey and Schmitz, 2002; Lema et al., 2015).
Recent studies have reviewed the literature that focuses
on the different theoretical perspectives in global supply
chain management (Connelly et al., 2013). However, a
com-
prehensive review of the literature dealing with the state
of the art of the global value chain configuration has not
yet been carried out. Firms are constantly taking decisions
http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.brq.2016.11.001
2340-9436/© 2016 ACEDE. Published by Elsevier España,
S.L.U. This is an open access article under the CC BY-NC-ND
license (http://
creativecommons.org/licenses/by-nc-nd/4.0/).
dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.brq.2016.11.001
http://www.elsevier.es/brq
http://crossmark.crossref.org/dialog/?doi=10.1016/j.brq.2016.11
.001&domain=pdf
http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by-nc-nd/4.0/
http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by-nc-nd/4.0/
http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by-nc-nd/4.0/
http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by-nc-nd/4.0/
http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by-nc-nd/4.0/
http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by-nc-nd/4.0/
http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by-nc-nd/4.0/
http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by-nc-nd/4.0/
http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by-nc-nd/4.0/
http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by-nc-nd/4.0/
mailto:[email protected]
mailto:[email protected]
dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.brq.2016.11.001
http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by-nc-nd/4.0/
http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by-nc-nd/4.0/
http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by-nc-nd/4.0/
http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by-nc-nd/4.0/
http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by-nc-nd/4.0/
http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by-nc-nd/4.0/
http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by-nc-nd/4.0/
http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by-nc-nd/4.0/
http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by-nc-nd/4.0/
http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by-nc-nd/4.0/
138 V. Hernández, T. Pedersen
Governance Location Coordination Performance Upgrading
The global valu e chain configu ration
Concept and activiti es Dec isions Implication s
Figure 1 Topics covered in this literature review.
in an interconnected world that not only affect their struc-
tures, capabilities and results, but also those of the other
agents they interact with. It is thus necessary to clearly
identify the decisions involved in a global value chain
con-
figuration that have been already examined and, from that,
the aspects that remain unexplored. The purpose of this
article is therefore to review the literature on global value
chain configurations in order to systematize it and indicate
avenues for future research (see Fig. 1).
The study contributes to global value chain literature in
several ways. We believe that, traditionally, research has
been focused on specific topics involved in its
configuration
such as decisions on location, governance and
coordination.
A review examining all of them allows us to better
under-
stand not only the characteristics of each decision but
also
the interdependencies between them. Additionally, it allows
us to observe the complexity of a global value chain con-
figuration that may be constantly evolving due to changes
in countries, industries and firms. All in all, it allows us
to
identify the topics that remain unexplored and present
those
lines of research that, in our view, remain unanswered.
The rest of the paper is structured as follows. First, we
explain the global value chain concept and the different
activities composing it. Secondly, we describe how the
liter-
ature has classified the different value chain configurations
and the key decisions in designing the global value chain,
namely governance, geographical scope and coordination
of activities. Thirdly, we explore the outcomes related to
global value chain configurations in terms of performance
and upgrading. Finally, we suggest future lines of research
and establish the conclusions that can be drawn from the
study.
Global value chains: concept and activities
Over the years, scholars have analyzed different termi-
nology to define how firms organize activities such as
commodity chains (Gereffi and Korzeniewicz, 1994;
Selwyn,
2015), supply chains (Al-Mudimigh et al., 2004; Connelly
et al., 2013; Priem and Swink, 2012), value networks
(de Reuver and Bouwman, 2012; Stabell and Fjeldstad,
1998), etc., depending on the specific relationships that
have emerged among firms and other agents within it
(Gereffi et al., 2001). Commodity chains focus on exam-
ining industries and the authority and power relationships
that have emerged within them to explain the role of a
leading firm (Mahutga, 2012) --- the firm which shapes,
con-
trols, coordinates and distributes the value along the chain
(Azmeh and Nadvi, 2014). A distinction has thus been
made
between buyer-driven commodity chains --- in which the
leading corporation plays a central role as merchandiser
and
makes sure that all pieces of the business come together
--- and producer-driven commodity chains --- in which the
leading corporation plays a central role in production
activ-
ities (Gereffi and Korzeniewicz, 1994). Other scholars have
focused on the analysis of supply chains, where the
supply
chain concept explains the firms’ relationships with suppli-
ers and customers to deliver product or services at less
cost
(Christopher, 2005). The value chain concept goes a step
further, and explains that entities may be connected and
create a value which is a source of competitive advantage
(Al-Mudimigh et al., 2004; Stabell and Fjeldstad, 1998).
This
latter concept also takes into account the customers in a
privileged position (Cox, 1999), understanding their needs
and offering them value (Di Domenico et al., 2007), by
exam-
ining value creation and its capture (Gereffi and Lee,
2012).
Moreover, when the value chain involves a constellation
of organizational arrangements and firms that are intercon-
nected through a global network, the global value chain
concept emerges (De Marchi et al., 2014; Giroud and
Mirza,
2015; Mudambi and Puck, 2016). Hence, the global value
chain is defined as ‘‘the full range of activities that firms
and workers perform to bring a product from its concep-
tion to end use and beyond’’, that are carried out on a
global scale and that can be undertaken by one or more
firms (Gereffi and Fernandez-Stark, 2011, p. 4).
Specifically,
some scholars point toward a new system called the
‘‘global
factory’’ (Buckley, 2011; Buckley and Ghauri, 2004),
which
entails the organization of activities in a complex
configura-
tion. This system describes how firms may reduce location
and transaction costs by orchestrating the global value
chain
in such a way that all activities are linked by
international
flows of intermediate products that the MNC controls but
does not necessarily own, and where knowledge is increas-
ingly internalized (Buckley and Strange, 2015).
One of the crucial aspects of building an overview of
global value chain configuration is therefore an examina-
tion of the activities involved, which can be grouped
based
on different criteria (see Table 1). Porter (1991) differ-
entiates primary activities --- those related to producing,
delivering and marketing the product or service---from sup-
port activities. The latter are either related to creating and
sourcing inputs or else to those factors that are integral
to
the firm and facilitate the work of primary activities, such
as ensuring efficiency and effectiveness (Priem and Swink,
2012; Tansuchat et al., 2016). It is also possible to
distin-
guish between upstream and downstream activities, based
on their closeness to the exploitation of raw materials or
to the manufacturing and customization of the product,
respectively (Nicovich et al., 2007; Pananond, 2013; Singer
and Donoso, 2008; Verbeke et al., 2016). Mudambi (2008)
Global value chain configuration: A review and research
agenda 139
Table 1 Classification of activities in the value chain.
Criteria Classification Description Studies
Degree of involvement in the
production process
Primary activities Those including creation,
production, logistics,
marketing and customer
service.
Porter, 1991; Priem and Swink,
2012; Tansuchat et al., 2016
Support activities Those related to procurement,
technology development,
human resource management,
and general infrastructure.
Function in the value chain Upstream activities Those close
to the exploitation
of natural resources and raw
materials or those related to
design, basic and applied
research and the
commercialization of creative
endeavors.
Mudambi, 2008; Mudambi and
Puck, 2016; Nicovich et al.,
2007; Pananond, 2013; Singer
and Donoso, 2008; Verbeke
et al., 2016
Middle-end activities Those related to
manufacturing and logistics.
Downstream
activities
Those close to the ultimate
consumer that add value to the
product by manufacturing or
customization.
Those related to marketing,
advertising, brand
management, after-sales
services, etc.
Potential for competence
creation
Exploration-related
activities
Those that create new areas of
competence by extending the
firm’s capabilities and involving
new combinations of resources.
Cantwell and Mudambi, 2005;
Cantwell and Piscitello, 2015;
Ha and Giroud, 2015
Exploitation-related
activities
Those based on the existing
firm’s capabilities.
Potential for being a source of
competitive advantage
Core activities Activities which are distinctive
and crucial for competitive
advantage.
Espino-Rodríguez and
Rodríguez-Díaz, 2014; Gilley
and Rasheed, 2000;
Linares-Navarro et al., 2014;
McIvor, 2000; Quinn, 1999
Essential activities Those activities which are
complementary and important
for competitive advantage.
Non-core activities Those activities that give low
added value to the firm.
adds a third type called middle-end activities. Under this
last approach, upstream activities are those that involve
design and research, both basic and applied, and the com-
mercialization of creative endeavors; downstream activities
typically comprise marketing, advertising, brand manage-
ment, and after-sales services; and middle-end activities
are
related to manufacturing, standardized service delivery and
other repetitious processes in which commercialized proto-
types are implemented on a mass scale. Activities may
also
be divided by distinguishing between those related to
explo-
ration from those related to exploitation, based on whether
they are competence-creating activities --- such as those
that
are technologically advanced --- or competence-exploiting
activities --- such as those that imply local adaptation
while
deploying existing technologies (Cantwell and Mudambi,
2005; Cantwell and Piscitello, 2015; Ha and Giroud,
2015).
Other classifications take into account activities’ impor-
tance in terms of the firm’s competitive advantage and
distinguish between core and non-core activities (Espino-
Rodríguez and Rodríguez-Díaz, 2014; Gilley and Rasheed,
2000; McIvor, 2000) or between core, essential and non-
core
activities (Contractor et al., 2010; Quinn, 1999; Linares-
Navarro et al., 2014). According to this latter view, core
activities are those with high added-value, which are dis-
tinctive and crucial for competitive advantage, and are
supposed to be the ones the firm performs better than any
other company; essential activities are those needed for
sus-
taining profitable operations that are complementary and
important for competitive advantage; and non-core activi-
ties are those that can easily be outsourced.
140 V. Hernández, T. Pedersen
How firms configure this complex system of activities
requires an analysis of different decisions, and we will
exam-
ine these in the following sections.
Configuring a global value chain
The configuration of a global value chain has evolved in
recent decades. Initially, activities were defined in large
blocks ranging from low-end manufacturing and service
activities to R&D, design and engineering. More recently,
some scholars have pointed out that the value chain can
no longer be seen as a set of traditional activities, as
firms have engaged in a process of fine-slicing activities
(Beugelsdijk et al., 2009; Contractor et al., 2010;
Mudambi,
2008; Mudambi and Puck, 2016). This process of
generating
finer modules has several implications. On the one hand,
firms have improved their learning about their own
systems
or about organizing activities in new ways and specifying
connections among them; on the other, it has allowed
firms
to redefine their core and non-core activities, keeping the
true core activities in-house and allocating more resources,
time and effort to those activities they do best (Gilley
and
Rasheed, 2000; Linares-Navarro et al., 2014). It implies a
process of modularization that takes large groups of activi-
ties --- such as those related to R&D, production or
marketing
--- and disaggregates them into sub-activities (Contractor
et al., 2010). Indeed, specialization may give some firms
the opportunity to develop superior capabilities that give
them a competitive advantage (Jacobides and Winter,
2005).
Firms thus have to decide: how to organize their activities
--- keep them in house, go to the market or use mixed
modes
such as alliances with other firms (Castañer et al., 2014;
Gereffi et al., 2005), where to locate these activities
(Jensen
and Pedersen, 2011; Los et al., 2015; Mudambi and Puck,
2016), and how to coordinate them globally (Beugelsdijk
et al., 2009; Hansen et al., 2009). Moreover, firms have
to
take into account that these choices may change and
evolve
over time depending on the circumstances, and must there-
fore review them continuously (Buckley, 2011; Buckley
and
Ghauri, 2004).
Governance structures of the global value chain
Governance refers to ‘‘authority and power relation-
ships that determine how financial, material, and human
resources are allocated and flow within a [value] chain’’
(Gereffi and Korzeniewicz, 1994, p. 97). In international
business literature, two traditional governance modes have
explained how firms operate abroad: based on hierarchy or
on the market. In other words, firms have to deal with
the
make-or-buy decision enounced in the transaction cost the-
ory (Coase, 1937; Williamson, 1975). However, it seems
that
explaining the global configuration of value chain
activities
merely through a hierarchical or a market structure (the
two
extremes) is far from the reality. As Jacobides and
Billinger
(2006) explain, firms can also use alliances and generate
par-
tial integration with mixed modes. When global value
chains
are analyzed, a range of governance options thus emerge
(see Fig. 2).
At one end we find the market governance mode and at
the other, the hierarchy mode. The former implies
relatively
Relational
supplier
HighLow
Degree of explicit coordination
Degree of power asymm etry
Relati onal Capti ve HierarchyMarket Modular
Materials
End Use
V
al
ue
C
ha
in
s
Suppliers
Custome rs
Price
Component
and mat erial
suppliers
Component
and mat erial
suppliers
Turn-
key
Lead
firm
Lead
firm
Integrat ed
FirmLead
firm
Relational
supplier
Capti ve
suppliers
Figure 2 Global value chain governance modes (Gereffi et
al.,
2005, p. 89).
simple transactions between the firms involved. Under this
structure, buyers and suppliers along the value chain need
little cooperation and the cost of switching to new part-
ners is low for both. Price is the mechanism for reaching
the deal (Gereffi and Fernandez-Stark, 2011). The
tendency,
however, is that firms within the global value chain are
ever
more connected, creating a network of independent firms
orchestrated or coordinated by a leading firm, and
providing
a context of trust and power within volatile environments
(Buckley, 2016). At the other end, we find the hierarchi-
cal governance mode, which implies vertical integration
and
managerial control within the lead firm. Although it is
less
and less common to find firms integrating the whole value
chain, there is research that has focused on examining
global
Global value chains, rising power firms and economic and social up.docx
Global value chains, rising power firms and economic and social up.docx
Global value chains, rising power firms and economic and social up.docx
Global value chains, rising power firms and economic and social up.docx
Global value chains, rising power firms and economic and social up.docx
Global value chains, rising power firms and economic and social up.docx
Global value chains, rising power firms and economic and social up.docx
Global value chains, rising power firms and economic and social up.docx
Global value chains, rising power firms and economic and social up.docx
Global value chains, rising power firms and economic and social up.docx
Global value chains, rising power firms and economic and social up.docx
Global value chains, rising power firms and economic and social up.docx
Global value chains, rising power firms and economic and social up.docx
Global value chains, rising power firms and economic and social up.docx
Global value chains, rising power firms and economic and social up.docx
Global value chains, rising power firms and economic and social up.docx
Global value chains, rising power firms and economic and social up.docx
Global value chains, rising power firms and economic and social up.docx
Global value chains, rising power firms and economic and social up.docx
Global value chains, rising power firms and economic and social up.docx
Global value chains, rising power firms and economic and social up.docx
Global value chains, rising power firms and economic and social up.docx
Global value chains, rising power firms and economic and social up.docx
Global value chains, rising power firms and economic and social up.docx
Global value chains, rising power firms and economic and social up.docx
Global value chains, rising power firms and economic and social up.docx
Global value chains, rising power firms and economic and social up.docx
Global value chains, rising power firms and economic and social up.docx
Global value chains, rising power firms and economic and social up.docx
Global value chains, rising power firms and economic and social up.docx
Global value chains, rising power firms and economic and social up.docx
Global value chains, rising power firms and economic and social up.docx
Global value chains, rising power firms and economic and social up.docx
Global value chains, rising power firms and economic and social up.docx
Global value chains, rising power firms and economic and social up.docx
Global value chains, rising power firms and economic and social up.docx
Global value chains, rising power firms and economic and social up.docx
Global value chains, rising power firms and economic and social up.docx
Global value chains, rising power firms and economic and social up.docx
Global value chains, rising power firms and economic and social up.docx
Global value chains, rising power firms and economic and social up.docx
Global value chains, rising power firms and economic and social up.docx
Global value chains, rising power firms and economic and social up.docx
Global value chains, rising power firms and economic and social up.docx
Global value chains, rising power firms and economic and social up.docx
Global value chains, rising power firms and economic and social up.docx
Global value chains, rising power firms and economic and social up.docx
Global value chains, rising power firms and economic and social up.docx
Global value chains, rising power firms and economic and social up.docx
Global value chains, rising power firms and economic and social up.docx
Global value chains, rising power firms and economic and social up.docx
Global value chains, rising power firms and economic and social up.docx
Global value chains, rising power firms and economic and social up.docx
Global value chains, rising power firms and economic and social up.docx
Global value chains, rising power firms and economic and social up.docx
Global value chains, rising power firms and economic and social up.docx
Global value chains, rising power firms and economic and social up.docx
Global value chains, rising power firms and economic and social up.docx
Global value chains, rising power firms and economic and social up.docx
Global value chains, rising power firms and economic and social up.docx
Global value chains, rising power firms and economic and social up.docx
Global value chains, rising power firms and economic and social up.docx
Global value chains, rising power firms and economic and social up.docx
Global value chains, rising power firms and economic and social up.docx
Global value chains, rising power firms and economic and social up.docx
Global value chains, rising power firms and economic and social up.docx
Global value chains, rising power firms and economic and social up.docx
Global value chains, rising power firms and economic and social up.docx
Global value chains, rising power firms and economic and social up.docx
Global value chains, rising power firms and economic and social up.docx
Global value chains, rising power firms and economic and social up.docx
Global value chains, rising power firms and economic and social up.docx
Global value chains, rising power firms and economic and social up.docx
Global value chains, rising power firms and economic and social up.docx
Global value chains, rising power firms and economic and social up.docx
Global value chains, rising power firms and economic and social up.docx
Global value chains, rising power firms and economic and social up.docx
Global value chains, rising power firms and economic and social up.docx
Global value chains, rising power firms and economic and social up.docx
Global value chains, rising power firms and economic and social up.docx
Global value chains, rising power firms and economic and social up.docx
Global value chains, rising power firms and economic and social up.docx
Global value chains, rising power firms and economic and social up.docx
Global value chains, rising power firms and economic and social up.docx
Global value chains, rising power firms and economic and social up.docx
Global value chains, rising power firms and economic and social up.docx
Global value chains, rising power firms and economic and social up.docx
Global value chains, rising power firms and economic and social up.docx
Global value chains, rising power firms and economic and social up.docx
Global value chains, rising power firms and economic and social up.docx
Global value chains, rising power firms and economic and social up.docx
Global value chains, rising power firms and economic and social up.docx
Global value chains, rising power firms and economic and social up.docx
Global value chains, rising power firms and economic and social up.docx
Global value chains, rising power firms and economic and social up.docx
Global value chains, rising power firms and economic and social up.docx
Global value chains, rising power firms and economic and social up.docx
Global value chains, rising power firms and economic and social up.docx
Global value chains, rising power firms and economic and social up.docx
Global value chains, rising power firms and economic and social up.docx
Global value chains, rising power firms and economic and social up.docx
Global value chains, rising power firms and economic and social up.docx
Global value chains, rising power firms and economic and social up.docx
Global value chains, rising power firms and economic and social up.docx
Global value chains, rising power firms and economic and social up.docx
Global value chains, rising power firms and economic and social up.docx
Global value chains, rising power firms and economic and social up.docx
Global value chains, rising power firms and economic and social up.docx
Global value chains, rising power firms and economic and social up.docx
Global value chains, rising power firms and economic and social up.docx
Global value chains, rising power firms and economic and social up.docx
Global value chains, rising power firms and economic and social up.docx
Global value chains, rising power firms and economic and social up.docx
Global value chains, rising power firms and economic and social up.docx
Global value chains, rising power firms and economic and social up.docx
Global value chains, rising power firms and economic and social up.docx
Global value chains, rising power firms and economic and social up.docx
Global value chains, rising power firms and economic and social up.docx
Global value chains, rising power firms and economic and social up.docx
Global value chains, rising power firms and economic and social up.docx
Global value chains, rising power firms and economic and social up.docx

More Related Content

Similar to Global value chains, rising power firms and economic and social up.docx

Introductory Session to Global Value Chain
Introductory Session to Global Value ChainIntroductory Session to Global Value Chain
Introductory Session to Global Value ChainTogar Simatupang
 
An empirical assessment of the effect of corporate restructuring in the banki...
An empirical assessment of the effect of corporate restructuring in the banki...An empirical assessment of the effect of corporate restructuring in the banki...
An empirical assessment of the effect of corporate restructuring in the banki...Alexander Decker
 
Indonesian Economic Development towards Global Value Chains
Indonesian Economic Development towards Global Value ChainsIndonesian Economic Development towards Global Value Chains
Indonesian Economic Development towards Global Value Chainsijtsrd
 
5.[63 76]analysis of the impact of interest rate on the net assets of multina...
5.[63 76]analysis of the impact of interest rate on the net assets of multina...5.[63 76]analysis of the impact of interest rate on the net assets of multina...
5.[63 76]analysis of the impact of interest rate on the net assets of multina...Alexander Decker
 
voucher system
voucher systemvoucher system
voucher systemLiyaSmart
 
1Running hHead DEVELOPMENT ECONOMICSDevelopment Economics .docx
1Running hHead DEVELOPMENT ECONOMICSDevelopment Economics      .docx1Running hHead DEVELOPMENT ECONOMICSDevelopment Economics      .docx
1Running hHead DEVELOPMENT ECONOMICSDevelopment Economics .docxvickeryr87
 
BusinessEthcsInSMEunderTheShelterOfCorporateGovern
BusinessEthcsInSMEunderTheShelterOfCorporateGovernBusinessEthcsInSMEunderTheShelterOfCorporateGovern
BusinessEthcsInSMEunderTheShelterOfCorporateGovernKashif Ali
 
Gv cs report_2017
Gv cs report_2017Gv cs report_2017
Gv cs report_2017ananabeto
 
MBA Dissertation Sample on Globalization
MBA Dissertation Sample on GlobalizationMBA Dissertation Sample on Globalization
MBA Dissertation Sample on GlobalizationMBA Dissertation
 
Investigating The Effect of Organizational Innovation and the Use of Online B...
Investigating The Effect of Organizational Innovation and the Use of Online B...Investigating The Effect of Organizational Innovation and the Use of Online B...
Investigating The Effect of Organizational Innovation and the Use of Online B...IRJET Journal
 
Discovery of key factors that may influence the success of multinational ICT ...
Discovery of key factors that may influence the success of multinational ICT ...Discovery of key factors that may influence the success of multinational ICT ...
Discovery of key factors that may influence the success of multinational ICT ...Anand Sheombar
 
Intellectual capital: A modern model to measure the value creation in a business
Intellectual capital: A modern model to measure the value creation in a businessIntellectual capital: A modern model to measure the value creation in a business
Intellectual capital: A modern model to measure the value creation in a businessAI Publications
 
Running Head ECONOMICS AND ADMINISTRATION1ECONOMICS AND ADMI.docx
Running Head ECONOMICS AND ADMINISTRATION1ECONOMICS AND ADMI.docxRunning Head ECONOMICS AND ADMINISTRATION1ECONOMICS AND ADMI.docx
Running Head ECONOMICS AND ADMINISTRATION1ECONOMICS AND ADMI.docxtodd271
 
Automotive industry and crisis (sturgeon jun 2010)
Automotive industry and crisis (sturgeon   jun 2010)Automotive industry and crisis (sturgeon   jun 2010)
Automotive industry and crisis (sturgeon jun 2010)earemike
 
Characteristics of Nigerian Deposit Money Banks and Their Financial Outcome
Characteristics of Nigerian Deposit Money Banks and Their Financial OutcomeCharacteristics of Nigerian Deposit Money Banks and Their Financial Outcome
Characteristics of Nigerian Deposit Money Banks and Their Financial Outcomeijtsrd
 
Global Financial Outlook during the COVID-19 Pandemic: The role of effective ...
Global Financial Outlook during the COVID-19 Pandemic: The role of effective ...Global Financial Outlook during the COVID-19 Pandemic: The role of effective ...
Global Financial Outlook during the COVID-19 Pandemic: The role of effective ...AI Publications
 
CORPORATE GOVERNANCE - PAST AND PRESENT
CORPORATE GOVERNANCE - PAST AND PRESENTCORPORATE GOVERNANCE - PAST AND PRESENT
CORPORATE GOVERNANCE - PAST AND PRESENTYaron Shemesh
 
Financial Statements Analysis: Wealth Creation and Wealth Maximisation at Tel...
Financial Statements Analysis: Wealth Creation and Wealth Maximisation at Tel...Financial Statements Analysis: Wealth Creation and Wealth Maximisation at Tel...
Financial Statements Analysis: Wealth Creation and Wealth Maximisation at Tel...iosrjce
 
The Economic Development Of A Nation
The Economic Development Of A NationThe Economic Development Of A Nation
The Economic Development Of A NationKim Moore
 

Similar to Global value chains, rising power firms and economic and social up.docx (20)

Introductory Session to Global Value Chain
Introductory Session to Global Value ChainIntroductory Session to Global Value Chain
Introductory Session to Global Value Chain
 
An empirical assessment of the effect of corporate restructuring in the banki...
An empirical assessment of the effect of corporate restructuring in the banki...An empirical assessment of the effect of corporate restructuring in the banki...
An empirical assessment of the effect of corporate restructuring in the banki...
 
Indonesian Economic Development towards Global Value Chains
Indonesian Economic Development towards Global Value ChainsIndonesian Economic Development towards Global Value Chains
Indonesian Economic Development towards Global Value Chains
 
5.[63 76]analysis of the impact of interest rate on the net assets of multina...
5.[63 76]analysis of the impact of interest rate on the net assets of multina...5.[63 76]analysis of the impact of interest rate on the net assets of multina...
5.[63 76]analysis of the impact of interest rate on the net assets of multina...
 
document.pdf
document.pdfdocument.pdf
document.pdf
 
voucher system
voucher systemvoucher system
voucher system
 
1Running hHead DEVELOPMENT ECONOMICSDevelopment Economics .docx
1Running hHead DEVELOPMENT ECONOMICSDevelopment Economics      .docx1Running hHead DEVELOPMENT ECONOMICSDevelopment Economics      .docx
1Running hHead DEVELOPMENT ECONOMICSDevelopment Economics .docx
 
BusinessEthcsInSMEunderTheShelterOfCorporateGovern
BusinessEthcsInSMEunderTheShelterOfCorporateGovernBusinessEthcsInSMEunderTheShelterOfCorporateGovern
BusinessEthcsInSMEunderTheShelterOfCorporateGovern
 
Gv cs report_2017
Gv cs report_2017Gv cs report_2017
Gv cs report_2017
 
MBA Dissertation Sample on Globalization
MBA Dissertation Sample on GlobalizationMBA Dissertation Sample on Globalization
MBA Dissertation Sample on Globalization
 
Investigating The Effect of Organizational Innovation and the Use of Online B...
Investigating The Effect of Organizational Innovation and the Use of Online B...Investigating The Effect of Organizational Innovation and the Use of Online B...
Investigating The Effect of Organizational Innovation and the Use of Online B...
 
Discovery of key factors that may influence the success of multinational ICT ...
Discovery of key factors that may influence the success of multinational ICT ...Discovery of key factors that may influence the success of multinational ICT ...
Discovery of key factors that may influence the success of multinational ICT ...
 
Intellectual capital: A modern model to measure the value creation in a business
Intellectual capital: A modern model to measure the value creation in a businessIntellectual capital: A modern model to measure the value creation in a business
Intellectual capital: A modern model to measure the value creation in a business
 
Running Head ECONOMICS AND ADMINISTRATION1ECONOMICS AND ADMI.docx
Running Head ECONOMICS AND ADMINISTRATION1ECONOMICS AND ADMI.docxRunning Head ECONOMICS AND ADMINISTRATION1ECONOMICS AND ADMI.docx
Running Head ECONOMICS AND ADMINISTRATION1ECONOMICS AND ADMI.docx
 
Automotive industry and crisis (sturgeon jun 2010)
Automotive industry and crisis (sturgeon   jun 2010)Automotive industry and crisis (sturgeon   jun 2010)
Automotive industry and crisis (sturgeon jun 2010)
 
Characteristics of Nigerian Deposit Money Banks and Their Financial Outcome
Characteristics of Nigerian Deposit Money Banks and Their Financial OutcomeCharacteristics of Nigerian Deposit Money Banks and Their Financial Outcome
Characteristics of Nigerian Deposit Money Banks and Their Financial Outcome
 
Global Financial Outlook during the COVID-19 Pandemic: The role of effective ...
Global Financial Outlook during the COVID-19 Pandemic: The role of effective ...Global Financial Outlook during the COVID-19 Pandemic: The role of effective ...
Global Financial Outlook during the COVID-19 Pandemic: The role of effective ...
 
CORPORATE GOVERNANCE - PAST AND PRESENT
CORPORATE GOVERNANCE - PAST AND PRESENTCORPORATE GOVERNANCE - PAST AND PRESENT
CORPORATE GOVERNANCE - PAST AND PRESENT
 
Financial Statements Analysis: Wealth Creation and Wealth Maximisation at Tel...
Financial Statements Analysis: Wealth Creation and Wealth Maximisation at Tel...Financial Statements Analysis: Wealth Creation and Wealth Maximisation at Tel...
Financial Statements Analysis: Wealth Creation and Wealth Maximisation at Tel...
 
The Economic Development Of A Nation
The Economic Development Of A NationThe Economic Development Of A Nation
The Economic Development Of A Nation
 

More from whittemorelucilla

Database reports provide us with the ability to further analyze ou.docx
Database reports provide us with the ability to further analyze ou.docxDatabase reports provide us with the ability to further analyze ou.docx
Database reports provide us with the ability to further analyze ou.docxwhittemorelucilla
 
DataInformationKnowledge1.  Discuss the relationship between.docx
DataInformationKnowledge1.  Discuss the relationship between.docxDataInformationKnowledge1.  Discuss the relationship between.docx
DataInformationKnowledge1.  Discuss the relationship between.docxwhittemorelucilla
 
DataHole 12 Score6757555455555455575775655565656555655656556566643.docx
DataHole 12 Score6757555455555455575775655565656555655656556566643.docxDataHole 12 Score6757555455555455575775655565656555655656556566643.docx
DataHole 12 Score6757555455555455575775655565656555655656556566643.docxwhittemorelucilla
 
DataDestination PalletsTotal CasesCases redCases whiteCases organi.docx
DataDestination PalletsTotal CasesCases redCases whiteCases organi.docxDataDestination PalletsTotal CasesCases redCases whiteCases organi.docx
DataDestination PalletsTotal CasesCases redCases whiteCases organi.docxwhittemorelucilla
 
DataIllinois Tool WorksConsolidated Statement of Income($ in milli.docx
DataIllinois Tool WorksConsolidated Statement of Income($ in milli.docxDataIllinois Tool WorksConsolidated Statement of Income($ in milli.docx
DataIllinois Tool WorksConsolidated Statement of Income($ in milli.docxwhittemorelucilla
 
DataIDSalaryCompa-ratioMidpoint AgePerformance RatingServiceGender.docx
DataIDSalaryCompa-ratioMidpoint AgePerformance RatingServiceGender.docxDataIDSalaryCompa-ratioMidpoint AgePerformance RatingServiceGender.docx
DataIDSalaryCompa-ratioMidpoint AgePerformance RatingServiceGender.docxwhittemorelucilla
 
DataCity1997 Median Price1997 Change1998 Forecast1993-98 Annualize.docx
DataCity1997 Median Price1997 Change1998 Forecast1993-98 Annualize.docxDataCity1997 Median Price1997 Change1998 Forecast1993-98 Annualize.docx
DataCity1997 Median Price1997 Change1998 Forecast1993-98 Annualize.docxwhittemorelucilla
 
DataClientRoom QualityFood QualityService Quality1GPG2GGG3GGG4GPG5.docx
DataClientRoom QualityFood QualityService Quality1GPG2GGG3GGG4GPG5.docxDataClientRoom QualityFood QualityService Quality1GPG2GGG3GGG4GPG5.docx
DataClientRoom QualityFood QualityService Quality1GPG2GGG3GGG4GPG5.docxwhittemorelucilla
 
Database Project CharterBusiness CaseKhalia HartUnive.docx
Database Project CharterBusiness CaseKhalia HartUnive.docxDatabase Project CharterBusiness CaseKhalia HartUnive.docx
Database Project CharterBusiness CaseKhalia HartUnive.docxwhittemorelucilla
 
Databases selected Multiple databases...Full Text (1223 .docx
Databases selected Multiple databases...Full Text (1223  .docxDatabases selected Multiple databases...Full Text (1223  .docx
Databases selected Multiple databases...Full Text (1223 .docxwhittemorelucilla
 
Database SystemsDesign, Implementation, and ManagementCo.docx
Database SystemsDesign, Implementation, and ManagementCo.docxDatabase SystemsDesign, Implementation, and ManagementCo.docx
Database SystemsDesign, Implementation, and ManagementCo.docxwhittemorelucilla
 
DATABASE SYSTEMS DEVELOPMENT & IMPLEMENTATION PLAN1DATABASE SYS.docx
DATABASE SYSTEMS DEVELOPMENT & IMPLEMENTATION PLAN1DATABASE SYS.docxDATABASE SYSTEMS DEVELOPMENT & IMPLEMENTATION PLAN1DATABASE SYS.docx
DATABASE SYSTEMS DEVELOPMENT & IMPLEMENTATION PLAN1DATABASE SYS.docxwhittemorelucilla
 
Database Security Assessment Transcript You are a contracting office.docx
Database Security Assessment Transcript You are a contracting office.docxDatabase Security Assessment Transcript You are a contracting office.docx
Database Security Assessment Transcript You are a contracting office.docxwhittemorelucilla
 
Database Design Mid Term ExamSpring 2020Name ________________.docx
Database Design Mid Term ExamSpring 2020Name ________________.docxDatabase Design Mid Term ExamSpring 2020Name ________________.docx
Database Design Mid Term ExamSpring 2020Name ________________.docxwhittemorelucilla
 
Database Justification MemoCreate a 1-page memo for the .docx
Database Justification MemoCreate a 1-page memo for the .docxDatabase Justification MemoCreate a 1-page memo for the .docx
Database Justification MemoCreate a 1-page memo for the .docxwhittemorelucilla
 
Database Concept Maphttpwikieducator.orgCCNCCCN.docx
Database Concept Maphttpwikieducator.orgCCNCCCN.docxDatabase Concept Maphttpwikieducator.orgCCNCCCN.docx
Database Concept Maphttpwikieducator.orgCCNCCCN.docxwhittemorelucilla
 
Database Dump Script(Details of project in file)Mac1) O.docx
Database Dump Script(Details of project in file)Mac1) O.docxDatabase Dump Script(Details of project in file)Mac1) O.docx
Database Dump Script(Details of project in file)Mac1) O.docxwhittemorelucilla
 
Database Design 1. What is a data model A. method of sto.docx
Database Design 1.  What is a data model A. method of sto.docxDatabase Design 1.  What is a data model A. method of sto.docx
Database Design 1. What is a data model A. method of sto.docxwhittemorelucilla
 
DataAGEGENDERETHNICMAJORSEMHOUSEGPAHRSNEWSPAPTVHRSSLEEPWEIGHTHEIGH.docx
DataAGEGENDERETHNICMAJORSEMHOUSEGPAHRSNEWSPAPTVHRSSLEEPWEIGHTHEIGH.docxDataAGEGENDERETHNICMAJORSEMHOUSEGPAHRSNEWSPAPTVHRSSLEEPWEIGHTHEIGH.docx
DataAGEGENDERETHNICMAJORSEMHOUSEGPAHRSNEWSPAPTVHRSSLEEPWEIGHTHEIGH.docxwhittemorelucilla
 

More from whittemorelucilla (20)

Database reports provide us with the ability to further analyze ou.docx
Database reports provide us with the ability to further analyze ou.docxDatabase reports provide us with the ability to further analyze ou.docx
Database reports provide us with the ability to further analyze ou.docx
 
DataInformationKnowledge1.  Discuss the relationship between.docx
DataInformationKnowledge1.  Discuss the relationship between.docxDataInformationKnowledge1.  Discuss the relationship between.docx
DataInformationKnowledge1.  Discuss the relationship between.docx
 
DataHole 12 Score6757555455555455575775655565656555655656556566643.docx
DataHole 12 Score6757555455555455575775655565656555655656556566643.docxDataHole 12 Score6757555455555455575775655565656555655656556566643.docx
DataHole 12 Score6757555455555455575775655565656555655656556566643.docx
 
DataDestination PalletsTotal CasesCases redCases whiteCases organi.docx
DataDestination PalletsTotal CasesCases redCases whiteCases organi.docxDataDestination PalletsTotal CasesCases redCases whiteCases organi.docx
DataDestination PalletsTotal CasesCases redCases whiteCases organi.docx
 
DataIllinois Tool WorksConsolidated Statement of Income($ in milli.docx
DataIllinois Tool WorksConsolidated Statement of Income($ in milli.docxDataIllinois Tool WorksConsolidated Statement of Income($ in milli.docx
DataIllinois Tool WorksConsolidated Statement of Income($ in milli.docx
 
DataIDSalaryCompa-ratioMidpoint AgePerformance RatingServiceGender.docx
DataIDSalaryCompa-ratioMidpoint AgePerformance RatingServiceGender.docxDataIDSalaryCompa-ratioMidpoint AgePerformance RatingServiceGender.docx
DataIDSalaryCompa-ratioMidpoint AgePerformance RatingServiceGender.docx
 
DataCity1997 Median Price1997 Change1998 Forecast1993-98 Annualize.docx
DataCity1997 Median Price1997 Change1998 Forecast1993-98 Annualize.docxDataCity1997 Median Price1997 Change1998 Forecast1993-98 Annualize.docx
DataCity1997 Median Price1997 Change1998 Forecast1993-98 Annualize.docx
 
DataClientRoom QualityFood QualityService Quality1GPG2GGG3GGG4GPG5.docx
DataClientRoom QualityFood QualityService Quality1GPG2GGG3GGG4GPG5.docxDataClientRoom QualityFood QualityService Quality1GPG2GGG3GGG4GPG5.docx
DataClientRoom QualityFood QualityService Quality1GPG2GGG3GGG4GPG5.docx
 
Database Project CharterBusiness CaseKhalia HartUnive.docx
Database Project CharterBusiness CaseKhalia HartUnive.docxDatabase Project CharterBusiness CaseKhalia HartUnive.docx
Database Project CharterBusiness CaseKhalia HartUnive.docx
 
Databases selected Multiple databases...Full Text (1223 .docx
Databases selected Multiple databases...Full Text (1223  .docxDatabases selected Multiple databases...Full Text (1223  .docx
Databases selected Multiple databases...Full Text (1223 .docx
 
Database SystemsDesign, Implementation, and ManagementCo.docx
Database SystemsDesign, Implementation, and ManagementCo.docxDatabase SystemsDesign, Implementation, and ManagementCo.docx
Database SystemsDesign, Implementation, and ManagementCo.docx
 
DATABASE SYSTEMS DEVELOPMENT & IMPLEMENTATION PLAN1DATABASE SYS.docx
DATABASE SYSTEMS DEVELOPMENT & IMPLEMENTATION PLAN1DATABASE SYS.docxDATABASE SYSTEMS DEVELOPMENT & IMPLEMENTATION PLAN1DATABASE SYS.docx
DATABASE SYSTEMS DEVELOPMENT & IMPLEMENTATION PLAN1DATABASE SYS.docx
 
Database Security Assessment Transcript You are a contracting office.docx
Database Security Assessment Transcript You are a contracting office.docxDatabase Security Assessment Transcript You are a contracting office.docx
Database Security Assessment Transcript You are a contracting office.docx
 
Data.docx
Data.docxData.docx
Data.docx
 
Database Design Mid Term ExamSpring 2020Name ________________.docx
Database Design Mid Term ExamSpring 2020Name ________________.docxDatabase Design Mid Term ExamSpring 2020Name ________________.docx
Database Design Mid Term ExamSpring 2020Name ________________.docx
 
Database Justification MemoCreate a 1-page memo for the .docx
Database Justification MemoCreate a 1-page memo for the .docxDatabase Justification MemoCreate a 1-page memo for the .docx
Database Justification MemoCreate a 1-page memo for the .docx
 
Database Concept Maphttpwikieducator.orgCCNCCCN.docx
Database Concept Maphttpwikieducator.orgCCNCCCN.docxDatabase Concept Maphttpwikieducator.orgCCNCCCN.docx
Database Concept Maphttpwikieducator.orgCCNCCCN.docx
 
Database Dump Script(Details of project in file)Mac1) O.docx
Database Dump Script(Details of project in file)Mac1) O.docxDatabase Dump Script(Details of project in file)Mac1) O.docx
Database Dump Script(Details of project in file)Mac1) O.docx
 
Database Design 1. What is a data model A. method of sto.docx
Database Design 1.  What is a data model A. method of sto.docxDatabase Design 1.  What is a data model A. method of sto.docx
Database Design 1. What is a data model A. method of sto.docx
 
DataAGEGENDERETHNICMAJORSEMHOUSEGPAHRSNEWSPAPTVHRSSLEEPWEIGHTHEIGH.docx
DataAGEGENDERETHNICMAJORSEMHOUSEGPAHRSNEWSPAPTVHRSSLEEPWEIGHTHEIGH.docxDataAGEGENDERETHNICMAJORSEMHOUSEGPAHRSNEWSPAPTVHRSSLEEPWEIGHTHEIGH.docx
DataAGEGENDERETHNICMAJORSEMHOUSEGPAHRSNEWSPAPTVHRSSLEEPWEIGHTHEIGH.docx
 

Recently uploaded

Kisan Call Centre - To harness potential of ICT in Agriculture by answer farm...
Kisan Call Centre - To harness potential of ICT in Agriculture by answer farm...Kisan Call Centre - To harness potential of ICT in Agriculture by answer farm...
Kisan Call Centre - To harness potential of ICT in Agriculture by answer farm...Krashi Coaching
 
Class 11 Legal Studies Ch-1 Concept of State .pdf
Class 11 Legal Studies Ch-1 Concept of State .pdfClass 11 Legal Studies Ch-1 Concept of State .pdf
Class 11 Legal Studies Ch-1 Concept of State .pdfakmcokerachita
 
Contemporary philippine arts from the regions_PPT_Module_12 [Autosaved] (1).pptx
Contemporary philippine arts from the regions_PPT_Module_12 [Autosaved] (1).pptxContemporary philippine arts from the regions_PPT_Module_12 [Autosaved] (1).pptx
Contemporary philippine arts from the regions_PPT_Module_12 [Autosaved] (1).pptxRoyAbrique
 
Accessible design: Minimum effort, maximum impact
Accessible design: Minimum effort, maximum impactAccessible design: Minimum effort, maximum impact
Accessible design: Minimum effort, maximum impactdawncurless
 
CARE OF CHILD IN INCUBATOR..........pptx
CARE OF CHILD IN INCUBATOR..........pptxCARE OF CHILD IN INCUBATOR..........pptx
CARE OF CHILD IN INCUBATOR..........pptxGaneshChakor2
 
Incoming and Outgoing Shipments in 1 STEP Using Odoo 17
Incoming and Outgoing Shipments in 1 STEP Using Odoo 17Incoming and Outgoing Shipments in 1 STEP Using Odoo 17
Incoming and Outgoing Shipments in 1 STEP Using Odoo 17Celine George
 
Concept of Vouching. B.Com(Hons) /B.Compdf
Concept of Vouching. B.Com(Hons) /B.CompdfConcept of Vouching. B.Com(Hons) /B.Compdf
Concept of Vouching. B.Com(Hons) /B.CompdfUmakantAnnand
 
_Math 4-Q4 Week 5.pptx Steps in Collecting Data
_Math 4-Q4 Week 5.pptx Steps in Collecting Data_Math 4-Q4 Week 5.pptx Steps in Collecting Data
_Math 4-Q4 Week 5.pptx Steps in Collecting DataJhengPantaleon
 
SOCIAL AND HISTORICAL CONTEXT - LFTVD.pptx
SOCIAL AND HISTORICAL CONTEXT - LFTVD.pptxSOCIAL AND HISTORICAL CONTEXT - LFTVD.pptx
SOCIAL AND HISTORICAL CONTEXT - LFTVD.pptxiammrhaywood
 
How to Configure Email Server in Odoo 17
How to Configure Email Server in Odoo 17How to Configure Email Server in Odoo 17
How to Configure Email Server in Odoo 17Celine George
 
Separation of Lanthanides/ Lanthanides and Actinides
Separation of Lanthanides/ Lanthanides and ActinidesSeparation of Lanthanides/ Lanthanides and Actinides
Separation of Lanthanides/ Lanthanides and ActinidesFatimaKhan178732
 
“Oh GOSH! Reflecting on Hackteria's Collaborative Practices in a Global Do-It...
“Oh GOSH! Reflecting on Hackteria's Collaborative Practices in a Global Do-It...“Oh GOSH! Reflecting on Hackteria's Collaborative Practices in a Global Do-It...
“Oh GOSH! Reflecting on Hackteria's Collaborative Practices in a Global Do-It...Marc Dusseiller Dusjagr
 
The Most Excellent Way | 1 Corinthians 13
The Most Excellent Way | 1 Corinthians 13The Most Excellent Way | 1 Corinthians 13
The Most Excellent Way | 1 Corinthians 13Steve Thomason
 
KSHARA STURA .pptx---KSHARA KARMA THERAPY (CAUSTIC THERAPY)————IMP.OF KSHARA ...
KSHARA STURA .pptx---KSHARA KARMA THERAPY (CAUSTIC THERAPY)————IMP.OF KSHARA ...KSHARA STURA .pptx---KSHARA KARMA THERAPY (CAUSTIC THERAPY)————IMP.OF KSHARA ...
KSHARA STURA .pptx---KSHARA KARMA THERAPY (CAUSTIC THERAPY)————IMP.OF KSHARA ...M56BOOKSTORE PRODUCT/SERVICE
 
Enzyme, Pharmaceutical Aids, Miscellaneous Last Part of Chapter no 5th.pdf
Enzyme, Pharmaceutical Aids, Miscellaneous Last Part of Chapter no 5th.pdfEnzyme, Pharmaceutical Aids, Miscellaneous Last Part of Chapter no 5th.pdf
Enzyme, Pharmaceutical Aids, Miscellaneous Last Part of Chapter no 5th.pdfSumit Tiwari
 
Call Girls in Dwarka Mor Delhi Contact Us 9654467111
Call Girls in Dwarka Mor Delhi Contact Us 9654467111Call Girls in Dwarka Mor Delhi Contact Us 9654467111
Call Girls in Dwarka Mor Delhi Contact Us 9654467111Sapana Sha
 

Recently uploaded (20)

Kisan Call Centre - To harness potential of ICT in Agriculture by answer farm...
Kisan Call Centre - To harness potential of ICT in Agriculture by answer farm...Kisan Call Centre - To harness potential of ICT in Agriculture by answer farm...
Kisan Call Centre - To harness potential of ICT in Agriculture by answer farm...
 
Código Creativo y Arte de Software | Unidad 1
Código Creativo y Arte de Software | Unidad 1Código Creativo y Arte de Software | Unidad 1
Código Creativo y Arte de Software | Unidad 1
 
TataKelola dan KamSiber Kecerdasan Buatan v022.pdf
TataKelola dan KamSiber Kecerdasan Buatan v022.pdfTataKelola dan KamSiber Kecerdasan Buatan v022.pdf
TataKelola dan KamSiber Kecerdasan Buatan v022.pdf
 
Class 11 Legal Studies Ch-1 Concept of State .pdf
Class 11 Legal Studies Ch-1 Concept of State .pdfClass 11 Legal Studies Ch-1 Concept of State .pdf
Class 11 Legal Studies Ch-1 Concept of State .pdf
 
Contemporary philippine arts from the regions_PPT_Module_12 [Autosaved] (1).pptx
Contemporary philippine arts from the regions_PPT_Module_12 [Autosaved] (1).pptxContemporary philippine arts from the regions_PPT_Module_12 [Autosaved] (1).pptx
Contemporary philippine arts from the regions_PPT_Module_12 [Autosaved] (1).pptx
 
Staff of Color (SOC) Retention Efforts DDSD
Staff of Color (SOC) Retention Efforts DDSDStaff of Color (SOC) Retention Efforts DDSD
Staff of Color (SOC) Retention Efforts DDSD
 
Accessible design: Minimum effort, maximum impact
Accessible design: Minimum effort, maximum impactAccessible design: Minimum effort, maximum impact
Accessible design: Minimum effort, maximum impact
 
CARE OF CHILD IN INCUBATOR..........pptx
CARE OF CHILD IN INCUBATOR..........pptxCARE OF CHILD IN INCUBATOR..........pptx
CARE OF CHILD IN INCUBATOR..........pptx
 
Incoming and Outgoing Shipments in 1 STEP Using Odoo 17
Incoming and Outgoing Shipments in 1 STEP Using Odoo 17Incoming and Outgoing Shipments in 1 STEP Using Odoo 17
Incoming and Outgoing Shipments in 1 STEP Using Odoo 17
 
Concept of Vouching. B.Com(Hons) /B.Compdf
Concept of Vouching. B.Com(Hons) /B.CompdfConcept of Vouching. B.Com(Hons) /B.Compdf
Concept of Vouching. B.Com(Hons) /B.Compdf
 
9953330565 Low Rate Call Girls In Rohini Delhi NCR
9953330565 Low Rate Call Girls In Rohini  Delhi NCR9953330565 Low Rate Call Girls In Rohini  Delhi NCR
9953330565 Low Rate Call Girls In Rohini Delhi NCR
 
_Math 4-Q4 Week 5.pptx Steps in Collecting Data
_Math 4-Q4 Week 5.pptx Steps in Collecting Data_Math 4-Q4 Week 5.pptx Steps in Collecting Data
_Math 4-Q4 Week 5.pptx Steps in Collecting Data
 
SOCIAL AND HISTORICAL CONTEXT - LFTVD.pptx
SOCIAL AND HISTORICAL CONTEXT - LFTVD.pptxSOCIAL AND HISTORICAL CONTEXT - LFTVD.pptx
SOCIAL AND HISTORICAL CONTEXT - LFTVD.pptx
 
How to Configure Email Server in Odoo 17
How to Configure Email Server in Odoo 17How to Configure Email Server in Odoo 17
How to Configure Email Server in Odoo 17
 
Separation of Lanthanides/ Lanthanides and Actinides
Separation of Lanthanides/ Lanthanides and ActinidesSeparation of Lanthanides/ Lanthanides and Actinides
Separation of Lanthanides/ Lanthanides and Actinides
 
“Oh GOSH! Reflecting on Hackteria's Collaborative Practices in a Global Do-It...
“Oh GOSH! Reflecting on Hackteria's Collaborative Practices in a Global Do-It...“Oh GOSH! Reflecting on Hackteria's Collaborative Practices in a Global Do-It...
“Oh GOSH! Reflecting on Hackteria's Collaborative Practices in a Global Do-It...
 
The Most Excellent Way | 1 Corinthians 13
The Most Excellent Way | 1 Corinthians 13The Most Excellent Way | 1 Corinthians 13
The Most Excellent Way | 1 Corinthians 13
 
KSHARA STURA .pptx---KSHARA KARMA THERAPY (CAUSTIC THERAPY)————IMP.OF KSHARA ...
KSHARA STURA .pptx---KSHARA KARMA THERAPY (CAUSTIC THERAPY)————IMP.OF KSHARA ...KSHARA STURA .pptx---KSHARA KARMA THERAPY (CAUSTIC THERAPY)————IMP.OF KSHARA ...
KSHARA STURA .pptx---KSHARA KARMA THERAPY (CAUSTIC THERAPY)————IMP.OF KSHARA ...
 
Enzyme, Pharmaceutical Aids, Miscellaneous Last Part of Chapter no 5th.pdf
Enzyme, Pharmaceutical Aids, Miscellaneous Last Part of Chapter no 5th.pdfEnzyme, Pharmaceutical Aids, Miscellaneous Last Part of Chapter no 5th.pdf
Enzyme, Pharmaceutical Aids, Miscellaneous Last Part of Chapter no 5th.pdf
 
Call Girls in Dwarka Mor Delhi Contact Us 9654467111
Call Girls in Dwarka Mor Delhi Contact Us 9654467111Call Girls in Dwarka Mor Delhi Contact Us 9654467111
Call Girls in Dwarka Mor Delhi Contact Us 9654467111
 

Global value chains, rising power firms and economic and social up.docx

  • 1. Global value chains, rising power firms and economic and social upgrading falseLee, Joonkoo; Gereffi, GaryAuthor Information . Critical Perspectives on International Business; Bradford11.3/4 (2015): 319-339. 1. Full text 2. Full text - PDF 3. Abstract/Details Abstract Translate AbstractUndo Translation TranslateUndo Translation Press the Escape key to close FromTo Translate Translation in progress... [[missing key: loadingAnimation]] The full text may take 40-60 seconds to translate; larger documents may take longer. Cancel OverlayEnd Purpose - The purpose of this paper is to introduce the global value chain (GVC) approach to understand the relationship between multinational enterprises (MNEs) and the changing patterns of global trade, investment and production, and its impact on economic and social upgrading. It aims to illuminate how GVCs can advance our understanding about MNEs and rising power (RP) firms and their impact on economic and social upgrading in fragmented and dispersed global production systems. Design/methodology/approach
  • 2. - The paper reviews the GVC literature focusing on two conceptual elements of the GVC approach, governance and upgrading, and highlights three key recent developments in GVCs: concentration, regionalization and synergistic governance. Findings - The paper underscores the complicated role of GVCs in shaping economic and social upgrading for emerging economies, RP firms and developing country firms in general. Rising geographic and organizational concentration in GVCs leads to the uneven distribution of upgrading opportunities in favor of RP firms, and yet economic upgrading may be elusive even for the most established suppliers because of power asymmetry with global buyers. Shifting end markets and the regionalization of value chains can benefit RP firms by presenting alternative markets for upgrading. Yet, without further upgrading, such benefits may be achieved at the expense of social downgrading. Finally, the ineffectiveness of private standards to achieve social upgrading has led to calls for synergistic governance through the cooperation of private, public and social actors, both global and local. Originality/value - The paper illuminates how the GVC approach and its key concepts can contribute to the critical international business and RP firms literature by examining the latest dynamics in GVCs and their impacts on economic and social development in developing countries. Purpose - The purpose of this paper is to introduce the global value chain (GVC) approach to understand the relationship between multinational enterprises (MNEs) and the changing patterns of global trade, investment and production, and its impact on economic and social upgrading. It aims to illuminate how GVCs can advance our understanding about MNEs and rising power (RP) firms and their impact on economic and social upgrading in fragmented and dispersed global production systems.
  • 3. Design/methodology/approach - The paper reviews the GVC literature focusing on two conceptual elements of the GVC approach, governance and upgrading, and highlights three key recent developments in GVCs: concentration, regionalization and synergistic governance. Findings - The paper underscores the complicated role of GVCs in shaping economic and social upgrading for emerging economies, RP firms and developing country firms in general. Rising geographic and organizational concentration in GVCs leads to the uneven distribution of upgrading opportunities in favor of RP firms, and yet economic upgrading may be elusive even for the most established suppliers because of power asymmetry with global buyers. Shifting end markets and the regionalization of value chains can benefit RP firms by presenting alternative markets for upgrading. Yet, without further upgrading, such benefits may be achieved at the expense of social downgrading. Finally, the ineffectiveness of private standards to achieve social upgrading has led to calls for synergistic governance through the cooperation of private, public and social actors, both global and local. Originality/value - The paper illuminates how the GVC approach and its key concepts can contribute to the critical international business and RP firms literature by examining the latest dynamics in GVCs and their impacts on economic and social development in developing countries. You have requested "on-the-fly" machine translation of selected content from our databases. This functionality is provided solely for your convenience and is in no way intended to replace human translation. Show full disclaimer Neither ProQuest nor its licensors make any representations or warranties with respect to the translations. The translations are automatically generated "AS IS" and "AS AVAILABLE" and are not retained in our systems. PROQUEST AND ITS
  • 4. LICENSORS SPECIFICALLY DISCLAIM ANY AND ALL EXPRESS OR IMPLIED WARRANTIES, INCLUDING WITHOUT LIMITATION, ANY WARRANTIES FOR AVAILABILITY, ACCURACY, TIMELINESS, COMPLETENESS, NON-INFRINGMENT, MERCHANTABILITY OR FITNESS FOR A PARTICULAR PURPOSE. Your use of the translations is subject to all use restrictions contained in your Electronic Products License Agreement and by using the translation functionality you agree to forgo any and all claims against ProQuest or its licensors for your use of the translation functionality and any output derived there from. Hide full disclaimer Translations powered by LEC. Translations powered by LEC. Full Text · Translate Full textUndo Translation TranslateUndo Translation Press the Escape key to close FromTo Translate Translation in progress... [[missing key: loadingAnimation]] The full text may take 40-60 seconds to translate; larger documents may take longer. Cancel OverlayEnd · Turn on search term navigationTurn on search term navigation · Jump to first hit Listen Introduction With the growing influence of multinational enterprises (MNEs) in the global economy, their role in promoting economic growth in developing countries has been hotly debated. In the international business (IB) literature, the mainstream approach
  • 5. tends to assume the positive impact of MNEs on economic development. The general consensus is that foreign direct investment and the presence of MNEs will lead to economic development in the host country through the spillover of capital, technology, skills and knowledge (Ghauri and Yamin, 2009; Meyer, 2004). Economic development is considered as a byproduct of MNE operations, not a core objective of MNEs. However, there has been weak evidence to support the spillover argument (Farole and Winkler, 2014; Oetzel and Doh, 2009). This has led recent IB scholarship to challenge such arguments, shifting attention to a more realistic picture of the effects of MNEs on economic and social development. This critical perspective casts light on the potential damaging effects of MNEs on economic development through the "race to the bottom" and "immiserizing growth". At the same time, with positive development outcomes no longer guaranteed as a byproduct of MNE operations, this critical perspective questions why MNEs should be concerned about development in the host country and the potential constraints they may face in trying to achieve it (Gifford et al. , 2010; Meyer, 2004; Yamin and Sinkovics, 2009). Despite this renewed interest from a critical perspective, the IB literature has yet to develop a systematic understanding of the relationship between MNEs and developing economies (Ghauri and Yamin, 2009). A more robust conceptual framework is needed, particularly because of the rapid reorganization of industrial production on the global scale, as well as the varied ways in which the MNE orchestrates its value chains across countries and regions, and inside and outside its organizational boundaries (Buckley, 2009; De Marchi et al. , 2014). This controversy has been accentuated by the recent global economic recession (Cattaneo et al. , 2010; Gereffi, 2014). This reopens the question of how these changes in the global and organizational environment of MNEs (re)shape the possibilities and constraints of economic and social development in developing countries (Buckley and Ghauri, 2004).
  • 6. As a contribution to this framework-building effort, this article introduces the global value chain (GVC) approach to better understand the relationship between MNEs and the changing patterns of global trade, investment and production, as well as the impact of MNEs on local upgrading efforts in developing economies. The GVC literature is uniquely positioned to provide a bridge between the IB and development literatures. The GVC approach originated with issues like why some countries are more successful in achieving economic development than others, and these questions have recently expanded into the social impact of economic upgrading (Barrientos et al. , 2011; Gereffi and Kaplinsky, 2001; Gereffi and Korzeniewicz, 1994; Lee et al. , 2011). Unlike other streams of development studies, however, the primary focus of GVC analysis is on firms and the governance of inter-firm relations, thereby providing an entry point for investigating networked forms of MNEs and other IB concerns (Bair, 2005; Lee, 2010 for reviews). This article will show how firms that are organized in GVCs affect economic and social upgrading in both dispersed and concentrated production systems, and it will also identify new trends in the GVC system that should be more fully incorporated in the critical IB literature. First, we introduce the GVC approach by highlighting two key concepts - governance and upgrading - that are the building blocks of this framework. Second, we discuss the implications for emerging economies and rising power (RP) firms of three significant developments in post-crisis GVCs: geographic and organizational concentration, shifting end markets and regionalization and the rise of standards and synergistic governance. We conclude with some summary reflections on how the GVC approach adds value to the IB literature. Governance and upgrading: complementary perspectives on the global economy A GVC refers to "the full range of activities that firms and workers perform to bring a specific product from its conception
  • 7. to its end use and beyond" (Gereffi and Fernandez-Stark, 2011). Generally, it includes research and development (R & D), design, production, sales and marketing, consumption and recycling. A GVC approach views the global economy as a complex network linking together suppliers and buyers that are integrated and driven by MNEs as lead firms. GVCs have become an integral part of the global economy, reshaping the traditional patterns of international production and trade. According to UNCTAD (2013, pp. 133-135), 80 per cent of world trade now passes through GVCs, and the developing country share in global value-added trade doubled from 20 to 40 per cent between 1990 and 2010. While measuring employment creation by GVCs is difficult, one study of 39 countries estimates that GVCs have generated 88 million jobs (Jiang and Milberg, 2013). The GVC approach provides a holistic view of global industries from the vantage point of two key concepts: governance and upgrading. Governance highlights the top-down process whereby lead firms integrate geographically and organizationally dispersed economic activities. While GVC analysis shares a firm-centric approach with the IB literature, its focus goes beyond the hierarchical governance of a firm (i.e. vertical integration and headquarter-subunit relations), and extends to various forms of contractual and relational coordination between independent companies that span international borders (De Marchi et al. , 2014). In addition to these corporate forms of governance, the GVC approach also pays attention to public and social governance and the institutional factors that shape them (Gereffi et al. , 2005; Mayer, 2014). The concept of upgrading focuses on the bottom-up strategies used by countries, regions and local firms to maintain or improve their positions and outcomes in the global economy. The GVC approach does not simply assume that integration to GVCs leads to economic upgrading through positive spillovers, but seeks to establish under what conditions, particularly under
  • 8. what GVC governance arrangements, upgrading (or downgrading) is likely to occur (Barrientos et al. , 2011; Humphrey and Schmitz, 2002)[1]. GVC governance: driving, coordinating and normalizing GVC governance is defined as "authority and power relationships that determine how financial, material, and human resources are allocated and flow within a chain" (Gereffi, 1994, p. 97). Production processes in the globalization era have been fundamentally restructured through offshoring and outsourcing. Unlike vertical integration where internal control and corporate fiat are used to solve coordination problems within the boundary of a firm, global outsourcing involves governance mechanisms that span the activities of multiple firms across national boundaries. The GVC literature highlights three aspects of GVC governance: driving, coordinating and normalizing (Ponte and Sturgeon, 2014). "Governance as driving" focuses on the lead firms in diverse global industries whose market power and technological or marketing assets allow them to set the performance criteria in terms of price, quality and delivery standards that shape the behavior of their suppliers. The distinction between "producer-driven" and "buyer-driven" chains is seminal: it asserts that two types of lead firms - large manufacturers and global buyers (i.e. retailers, brands and supermarkets) - drive supply chains differently and pose distinct challenges for chain entry and upgrading (Gereffi, 1994; Gereffi and Lee, 2012). For example, while in buyer-driven chains, global buyers like Nike tend to own few or no factories and instead focus on product design, branding and marketing, their governance power extends well beyond their main contractors as their orders and specifications travel down to hundreds of lower-tier suppliers in their supply chain[2] (Donaghu and Barff, 1990). "Governance as coordination" highlights the varied forms of inter-firm linkages in GVCs. GVCs consist of multiple linkages that connect suppliers and buyers. The GVC approach extends
  • 9. the "market-hierarchy" dichotomy in transaction cost economics (Williamson, 1985) by offering a more elaborate typology of enduring inter-firm networks that characterize international supply chains. For example, Gereffi et al. (2005) identify five types of GVC governance: market (arms-length transactions) and hierarchy (vertical integration), along with three distinctive network-types (modular, relational and captive). The GVC perspective asserts that not all network forms of governance are alike. Also, it posits that the type of GVC governance that arises in a specific chain depends on a combination of three key factors: the complexity of inter-firm transactions, the codifiability of the transactions and suppliers' capability to meet buyers' requirements. Thus, the nature of transactions defines the form of governance that affects upgrading of the parties involved. While "governance as driving" relates to the entire chain (macro-level) and "governance as coordination" involves linkages at specific junctures in the chain (micro-level), "governance as normalizing" deals with the meso-level of GVC governance. Particularly, GVC scholars pay attention to various standards and relevant normative frameworks that shape the overall conditions of GVC participation and upgrading (Gibbon and Ponte, 2008; Ponte and Gibbon, 2005). Such standards allow a normative, or commonly agreed, element of coordination, such as defining rules, conventions and conditions of chain participation, to travel along the chain from one node to another, working as a mechanism "re-aligning a given practice to be compatible with a standard or norm" (Ponte and Sturgeon, 2014, p. 206). Recent GVC research has highlighted the interaction of multiple forms of governance. Challenging the existing notion of a unipolar structure of governance, where one set of firms - buyers or producers - has dominant power to govern, newer studies feature the role of bipolar or multi-polar GVC governance, where more complicated patterns of power relations emerge between lead firms in GVCs (Fold, 2002; Islam, 2008;
  • 10. Kawakami, 2011). For example, in the automobile industry, one of the paradigmatic producer-driven chains, the rise of "mega suppliers" is challenging the pre-eminent role of the carmakers as lead firms and altering the balance of power in the industry (Foy, 2014). There are now 16 major car manufacturers that sell more than 1 million vehicles per year, but those cars are built from parts supplied by just ten major component makers[3], meaning that auto assemblers are now reliant on a small cadre of mega suppliers who each sell parts to rival assemblers. Although the automakers are still considerably larger than the mega suppliers in sales, the latter are more profitable than the companies they sell to[4]. While mega suppliers are in a position to bargain more effectively with global automakers[5], the latter remain in the driver's seat in terms of overall governance of the automotive value chain because they determine when, where and at what price they will sell fully assembled vehicles to customers around the world. Upgrading: economic and social dimensions Upgrading refers to "a process of improving the ability of a firm or an economy to move to a more profitable and/or technologically sophisticated capital- and skill-intensive economic niche" (Gereffi, 1999, pp. 51-52). The concept originated in the observation that what matters for a country's development was less the overall level of industrialization than the type of chain activities they were involved in. In other words, a country or firm obtains bigger gains when they move up the value chain into higher value-added chains or nodes (Gereffi and Kaplinsky, 2001). A central argument of the GVC approach is that the type of governance structure significantly affects upgrading outcomes. Humphrey and Schmitz (2002) specify four types of upgrading, representing different "niches" where upgrading takes place: Process upgrading : Making production processes more efficient by reorganizing the production system and using advanced technology; Product upgrading : Moving into more sophisticated, or high-
  • 11. value, product lines; Functional upgrading : Occupying more profitable functional nodes within a chain; and Chain upgrading : Diversifying into more profitable value chains. GVC studies have found that product and process upgrading are facilitated by learning from global buyers, whereas global buyers do not necessarily facilitate functional upgrading (Schmitz, 2004). For example, in Brazil's Sinos Valley shoe cluster, tight coordination by foreign buyers created favorable conditions for local suppliers to achieve product and process upgrading (Bazan and Navas-Alemán, 2004). However, upgrading to higher-value activities like branding and design was constrained by a captive mode of governance (Giuliani et al. , 2005; Lee and Chen, 2000). Functional upgrading was out of reach when global buyers were reluctant to support it, or actively blocked it out of concern that it might bring greater competition (Bazan and Navas-Alemán, 2004). Similarly, American buyers contributed to the process and product upgrading of local blue jeans producers in Torreon, Mexico, giving rise to full-package production. Yet, more extensive functional upgrading did not take place because of the risks that such upgrading posed for MNE lead firms (Bair and Gereffi, 2001). In much of the GVC literature, there has been an implicit presumption that economic upgrading would lead to social gains, i.e. the improvement of the well-being of workers in the chains. Yet, recent evidence suggests that economic upgrading is often not accompanied by social upgrading, and indeed, it can worsen social conditions (Lee et al. , 2011). Social upgrading refers to the process of improvement in the rights and entitlements of workers as social actors and enhances the quality of their employment (Barrientos et al. , 2011). A series of studies from the Capturing the Gains research program[6] have found that upgrading is segmented. For example, regular workers may benefit from higher wages and strong labor
  • 12. standards as a result of economic upgrading, while many others, particularly women and migrant workers, are put in highly flexible, unprotected and insecure work. Poor jobs are fuelled by low productivity, subcontracting and suppliers struggling to meet buyers' requirements on product quality as well as social and environmental standards. Progress made in measurable standards (e.g. the size and type of employment, wages and working hours) may not extend to enabling rights (e.g. freedom of association and the right to collective bargaining), with many export sectors suffering an extremely low level of unionization (Barrientos et al. , 2012). In short, with the concepts of governance and upgrading, the GVC approach provides a firm-based, network-centric view of how MNEs as global lead firms affect economic and social development. The role of MNEs in promoting or inhibiting development extends beyond their hierarchical boundary to a series of GVC linkages they govern in various ways: driving, coordinating and normalizing. The GVC literature also suggests that the scope and speed of upgrading and the gains from it largely depend on a firm's position and the types of governance in place in the GVC, and economic upgrading does not necessarily lead to social upgrading. Changing GVC dynamics and the impacts on emerging economies and RP firms The global economy has undergone significant changes over the past two decades, and the emerging economies have been clear winners. Whereas the share of high-income countries in total value added that was generated in all manufacturing GVCs declined from 74 per cent in 1995 to 56 per cent in 2008, and the share of Japan and the East Asian newly industrializing economies (NIEs) declined from 21 to 11 per cent, emerging economies have increased their shares of value added in manufacturing by 18 per cent. China alone is responsible for half of this increase, with its global share rising rapidly from 4 to 13 per cent, but value added shares also increased in other emerging economies, including Brazil, Russia, India and
  • 13. Mexico (Timmer et al. , 2014, p. 109). During this same period, 42 million manufacturing jobs were added in China, 20 million in India, 6 million in Brazil and 2 million in Mexico (Timmer et al. , 2014, p. 112). More recently, the global recession of the late 2000s precipitated sharp shifts in global production and trade, with major implications for the role played by emerging economies and RP firms in GVCs (Cattaneo et al. , 2010; Gereffi, 2014). In this section, we discuss the key dynamics of GVCs in the post- crisis global economy from three angles: geographic and value chain concentration; shifting end markets and regionalization; and synergistic forms of GVC governance. However, this analysis should first be related to the growing literature on RPs and RP firms in IB studies. Nadvi (2014) has provided a clear and useful operational definition of "rising powers" that emphasizes six features: rapid and sustained economic growth; increasing participation in international trade with dominance in particular sectors; significant economic scale, including population, natural resources, a manufacturing base and a sizeable domestic market; a strong role of the state; local capital (both private and public) with an expanding international presence; and a growing voice for civil society. Although these large emerging economies (the term we will use in this article) were initially associated with the BRICs (Brazil, Russia, India and China), they now include more than a dozen countries with similar features, including Mexico, Indonesia, Nigeria and Turkey (the "MINT" countries), South Africa and others (Sinkovics et al. , 2014b). While the emerging economies indeed play a central role in GVC analysis, the more controversial issue is the status of RP firms. If "rising powers" refer to countries such as China, India, Brazil, Russia and South Africa, which are on rapid economic growth and development trajectories, then RP firms can be thought of as emergent and with a clear strategic intent to challenge the Western and dominant forms of economic organization (Sinkovics and Yamin, 2012). A more contentious
  • 14. issue, however, is whether RP firms are merely emulating or "catching up" with MNEs from the advanced industrial economies, or whether they are fundamentally "changing the rules of the game" in the contemporary global economy (Sinkovics et al. , 2014b). Within the traditional IB literature, the paradigm typically used to address this question is John Dunning's eclectic ownership, location, and internalization (OLI) model[7] (Luo and Tung, 2007), sometimes supplemented with insights from the "late comer" perspective introduced by economic historian Alexander Gerschenkron[8] (Sinkovics et al. , 2014b). From a GVC perspective, there are three shortcomings in the current literature on RP firms. First, the characterization of RP firms tends to reflect an outmoded view of the global economy centered on large national markets and asset-seeking MNEs. In a GVC-oriented world, value creation, value capture and economic rents occur in more fluid international production networks, where the ability to shape innovation processes and labor and environmental outcomes often resides in the distribution and retail segments of GVCs (Hamilton et al. , 2011), and not only in the production activities and OLI advantages of RP manufacturing and resource-based firms. The varied nature of GVC governance structures is typically absent in the analysis of RP firms. Second, the RP literature usually tries to categorize RP firms as different in kind from MNEs in the earlier set of East Asia's NIEs, namely, Hong Kong, Taiwan, Singapore and South Korea (Luo and Tung, 2007, p. 483). While there clearly are key distinctions between today's emerging economies and the East Asian NIEs, beginning with economic scale, notable examples exist where MNEs from the NIEs are tightly integrated into the economies of rising powers, especially China, and indeed link them to the global economy in significant ways that have been directly responsible for the economic dynamism that is one of the defining features of the RP. Li & Fung, the largest trading company in the world, is headquartered in Hong Kong but does
  • 15. most of its sourcing from China[9]. Similarly, Foxconn Technology Group, the largest electronics contract manufacturer in the world, has its home office in Taiwan, but its production and exports for leading brand name multinationals like Apple are concentrated in mainland China, where it employs more than 1 million workers, making it by far the largest private employer in the country. In terms of GVC dynamics, Li & Fung and Foxconn act like RP firms, even if their headquarters are elsewhere[10]. Third, one of the most persuasive arguments for the transformative potential of RP firms is that they are now pursuing their own low-cost innovation strategies and trying to leverage the growing size of the low- and middle-income segments in emerging economies to seek "gold at the base of the pyramid" and to win the "fight for the middle" in RP markets, while advanced country MNEs are engaged in "a race to the top" (Sinkovics et al. , 2014b, p. 677). This indeed could be a very profitable upgrading approach, but it is not limited to RP firms. The business press is full of entrepreneurial initiatives being launched by innovative companies all around the world and not just in emerging economies, which are empowered by the use of the Internet, pervasive digital technologies and crowd-sourced venture capital to solve basic development problems, like the Chilean entrepreneur who found a cheap way to give hundreds of millions of people in the world access to clean drinking water (Wadhwa, 2013). Furthermore, one of the leading RP firms, China-based Lenovo Group, the top vendor of personal computers globally, is anchoring its new PC Plus strategy (based on moving beyond PCs into smartphones, tablets and servers) not in the China market, but in North America (Oleniacz, 2014). The discussion below of recent GVC trends will further illustrate these and other points related to emerging economies and RP firms. The geographic and organizational concentration of GVCs Over the past decade, GVCs have become significantly more
  • 16. concentrated, both geographically and organizationally. Despite the initial expectation that the global spread and fragmentation of production activities might lead to greater participation by less-developed countries and smaller firms in GVCs, recent evidence in a number of industries, from apparel to automobiles, electronics and even services, suggests that GVCs are becoming geographically concentrated in fewer countries, especially emerging economies with large domestic markets and robust supplier bases, such as Brazil, China, India and South Africa (Cattaneo et al. , 2010). The trend has been intensified by the global recession as GVC lead firms streamlined their supply chains to focus on a smaller number of large, more capable suppliers, which are strategically located near dynamic nodes of GVCs (Gereffi, 2014). The example of mobile phones is illustrative (Lee and Gereffi, 2013). Until the late 1990s, the entire production of mobile phones was conducted in advanced economies. The ensuing rise of global outsourcing has shifted production to developing countries. The five largest exporters - China, South Korea, Hong Kong, Vietnam and the USA - commanded 74 per cent of the world ' s exports in 2012, with China alone representing a half of them[11] (Lee and Gereffi, 2013). As a result, mobile phone production today is clustered in several countries in Asia, notably China, South Korea and Vietnam. Moreover, the key nodes of mobile phone GVCs are significantly consolidated. The five leading firms account for more than a half of global markets in mobile phones (56 per cent), smartphones (60 per cent), contract manufacturing (75 per cent) and smartphone operating systems (99 per cent). Two leading firms control a big portion of each market, such as Apple and Samsung in smartphones, which gives rise to oligopolistic market structures[12]. There are several implications of this rising concentration in GVCs. First, upgrading opportunities are unevenly distributed among countries and firms, and concentration amplifies the benefits of inclusion and the disadvantages of exclusion in
  • 17. GVCs. As a significant proportion of world production and exports is dominated by a handful of countries, the vast majority of countries and firms are marginalized with few linkages to global industries and limited upgrading prospects. Also, the rise of large RP countries as the prominent locations for GVC production puts pressure on other countries to cut costs and squeeze their profits to compete. As a result, the geography of production - which countries are in or out - is heavily affected by the decisions of a few global brands and their key contract manufacturers. For RP firms, rising geographic and value chain concentration has increased their influence in GVCs. They clearly benefit from the concentration of production in emerging economies, and at the same time, their growing capabilities enable global lead firms to shift more production to these countries. For example, East Asian contract manufacturers like Foxconn have taken advantage of capable supplier bases clustered in China, as exemplified by its supply chain cities (Gereffi, 2009), and neighboring East Asian countries. As global lead firms like Apple and Hewlett-Packard are keen to tap into more capable suppliers, RP firms are better positioned to serve global firms and advance their positions in GVCs. The rise of large consolidated, transnational suppliers in RP economies generates the expectation that they may check the power of global lead firms (Appelbaum, 2008). Actual upgrading outcomes, however, are less straightforward. Some RP firms are big, capable and transnational, but power asymmetries in their relationship with their global buyers still cannot be ignored. For example, Apple's iPods and iPhones are almost entirely assembled in China by Foxconn and Pegatron, two of the biggest electronics contract manufacturers. Yet, the value captured by these global contract manufacturers is extremely small compared to the gains by Apple and other high- end component suppliers in Japan, Korea and Germany[13] (Dedrick et al. , 2011). Thin margins and the fast pace of production virtually dictated by buyers significantly hamper
  • 18. their ability to improve labor conditions for workers, even after a series of worker suicides sparked widespread criticism and intense scrutiny from the public and the media (Chan et al. , 2013; Lee and Gereffi, 2013). The extent to which RP firms can contribute to the upgrading of smaller, less capable suppliers is limited. There is some expectation that RP firms can facilitate the transfer of technology and knowledge to smaller firms in the chain. But the extent to which RP firms can deliver these results depends on their abilities and strategies to capture more value in GVCs. For instance, Foxconn manufactures many parts and components in- house as a way to compensate for slim margins in its contract manufacturing business (Balfour and Culpan, 2010); this can limit, if not completely eliminate, their ability to help the upgradation of smaller suppliers. Furthermore, there continue to be questions about the innovative impact of RP firms. Despite China's push for greater technological autonomy and indigenous innovation, its high- tech sectors and export performance are still heavily dependent on foreign-invested enterprises. Of the top 20 exporting firms based in China in 2012, only 2 were Chinese-owned: Huawei and ZTE. Twelve of the top 20 exporters were based in Taiwan (including 6 companies owned by Foxconn), and 4 were from South Korea (Grimes and Sun, 2014, p. 66). Shifting end markets and regionalized value chains In the post-war world economy, international trade was premised on the fact that most final products were consumed in developed economies. Upgrading basically meant serving buyers from advanced economies. For example, export-oriented industrialization fuelled rapid economic development in the NIEs, which oriented their development strategies to the export of manufactured goods to US and European markets, and Western lead firms knew best how to cater to consumers in these markets (Hamilton and Gereffi, 2009). This conventional flow of international trade, however, began to change in the mid-1980s due to economic slumps in the global
  • 19. North and rapidly growing market demand in the NIEs. In 1990, 60 per cent of the world trade was between developed countries (North-North), 30 per cent was between industrialized and developing countries (North-South) and 10 per cent was South- South. By 2020, these three patterns of trade are expected to be equally split, meaning that the relative weight of North-North trade will have been cut in half in just 30 years (Lamy, 2013). A major part of this shift is being driven by the fact that almost 60 per cent of trade in goods is now in intermediate products that are used as imports in the production process, especially for exports - the so-called GVC trade (UNCTAD, 2013). While the import content of exports was 20 per cent in 1990, this increased to 40 per cent in 2010 and it is expected to be 60 per cent in 2030 (Lamy, 2013). The resulting shift of end markets to emerging economies was exacerbated by the 2008-2009 global recession. It had a major impact on developed economies, while large RP countries like China, India and Brazil fared relatively better (Gereffi and Sturgeon, 2013). As world trade bounced back from the economic crises, developing economies became the main engine of the recovery (Staritz et al. , 2011). These emerging economies, unlike the East Asian NIEs, have much bigger domestic markets and are rich in natural resources. In 2005- 2010, the merchandise imports of the European Union and the USA increased only by 27 and 14 per cent, respectively, while emerging economies expanded their merchandise imports much faster: Brazil (147 per cent), India (129 per cent), China (111 per cent) and South Africa (51 per cent) (WTO, 2011). The import growth in emerging economies is also driven by rising demand for intermediate goods and raw materials because manufacturing GVCs are concentrated in those economies, as discussed above (Kaplinsky et al. , 2011). The economic downturn in advanced industrial countries and the rise of large emerging economies has fueled the regionalization of value chains. Regional production networks emerged as factories and suppliers linked through GVCs were clustered into
  • 20. a reduced number of strategically located countries. A notable example is the East Asian regional production network. Strong supply bases, different levels of industrial capabilities and complementarities between countries for financial, technological and human resources help the growth of cross- national production networks in the region. In electronics, for instance, many high-end components are supplied from Japan, Korea and Taiwan, which have strong R & D capabilities, and assembled in China with low-end components produced locally or in other developing countries, such as Vietnam and the Philippines (WTO and IDE-JETRO, 2011). While such regional divisions of labor are not new (Borrus et al. , 2000; Gereffi, 1996), nowadays more products in diverse industries are made and consumed regionally instead of being exported to advanced economies and RP firms play an active role in creating a regional circuit of production and consumption. In Sub-Saharan Africa (SSA), South African supermarkets are building up regional supply chains and spearheading the diffusion of supermarkets across the region. So are the supermarkets from Kenya, but on a different geographic scale. At the same time, the South African, Kenyan and Ugandan producers have found new markets in the Middle East and Asia. This provides SSA farmers and producers with the alternative buyers to global supermarket chains, leading to the rise of new South-South value chains (Barrientos and Visser, 2012; Evers et al. , 2014). Similarly, South African clothing manufacturers recently entered into neighboring countries like Lesotho and Swaziland to serve mainly South African and other SSA markets. They work with clients like South African retailers, who also are expanding regionally (Morris et al. , 2011). The regionalization of value chains is also driven by global lead firms. They tend to focus on a group of countries that are proximate geographically, economically or socio-linguistically to promote their localization strategies. Wal-Mart, for example, has expanded its retail network across SSA with a regional scale
  • 21. of sourcing, logistics and distribution operations. Similarly, Vodafone, a UK-based, multinational mobile service provider, operates across the SSA region to compete against major RP telecom companies that operate regionally, such as MTN of South Africa and Bharti Airtel of India. In this way, global regions have become a locus of competition between local, regional and global firms, which accelerates the regionalization of value chains. The regionalization of value chains can provide RP firms with some upgrading advantages. First, regional markets and value chains may present alternative economic upgrading paths where RP firms may have better chances for functional upgrading than in global chains (Bazan and Navas-Alemán, 2004; Morris et al. , 2011). Less stringent standards and lower entry barriers with less capital and technology requirements in regional value chains or Southern markets can facilitate smaller firms in emerging economies to participate in exports and other forms of business abroad. Second, RP firms can leverage their experience and knowledge of local and regional markets in the global South to gain advantages over global firms, which often suffer from a "liability of outsidership", or a lack of in-depth understanding of such markets (Johanson and Vahlne, 2009; Sinkovics et al. , 2014a). For example, the so-called "frugal innovations" (Clark et al. , 2009) - developing products or services especially designed for resource-poor settings - may present RP firms with an opportunity to bypass global firms in serving Southern consumers, typically with lower incomes and poor services in power supply and transportation. Such businesses tend to be low in unit margins, but they can create a high-volume market by tapping into a large population of new Southern consumers. However, there are potential downsides for RP firms. The lower entry barriers of regional or South-South value chains may work against RP firms if they are stuck in a low-cost, low-standard market. Furthermore, the advantage of their intimate knowledge in local markets may not last for long. For example, Chinese mobile phone makers faced greater competition in the domestic
  • 22. market as global brands like Nokia and Samsung, after struggling with localization, caught up fast and closed the gap with Chinese competitors in terms of understanding local markets (Brandt and Thun, 2011). Thus, local advantages in upgrading may be short-lived. The implications of regionalization for social upgrading are less clear. Compared to global or North-bound chains, less stringent social standards in regional value chains and the smaller premiums Southern consumers may be willing to pay for social labels could discourage RP firms from committing to an upgrading of working conditions in their supply chains. Also, the "high-volume, low-cost" model in Southern markets can have a negative impact on social upgrading for certain workers because firms in this model tend to rely on the extensive outsourcing of "non-core" activities to a large pool of contract workers whose employment tends to be less stable, as shown in the case of Indian information technology and telecom firms (Sarkar et al. , 2013). This may create favorable conditions for regular, skilled "core" workers, while contract workers suffer from precarious employment conditions. From private standards to synergistic governance As GVCs develop into multi-tier structures where firms in each tier outsource some of their activities, lead firms use their own standards to govern the chains and the behavior of the other chain actors involved. This gives rise to private standards (Mayer and Gereffi, 2010), which unlike public standards that are enforced mandatorily by governments, are promulgated and executed by firms, individually or collectively, and are voluntary in principle[14]. However, recent studies suggest a more limited role for lead firms and their private standards in facilitating upgrading, especially the social dimensions (Locke, 2013; Mayer and Gereffi, 2010), which has led to calls for synergistic forms of private, public and social governance (Gereffi et al. , 2014; Mayer, 2014)[15]. There are different types of private standards in GVCs (Ponte and Gibbon, 2005). Quality standards involve a wide range of
  • 23. product quality, including product safety. Quality standards, such as GLOBALGAP (Good Agricultural Practice), have become critical in GVCs as a number of firms in different countries affect the quality of final products. Growing demand for product differentiation among consolidated lead firms increases the need for private quality standards. Another expanding area is social and environmental standards (Nadvi, 2014). Global lead firms are increasingly facing public pressure to make their supply chains socially and environmentally sustainable. Any corporate wrongdoings in their supply chains could eventually inflict reputational damage on lead firms even if the factory is not owned by them. Private standards have upgrading implications for firms in developing countries (Humphrey, 2006; Lee et al. , 2012). Complying with standards requires commitments to various activities, from additional documentation to facility improvement, which incur added costs to the firms. Thus, standards can work as entry barriers for smaller suppliers or producers that tend to have limited resources. In agri-food chains, for example, large food manufacturers and supermarkets are increasingly rationalizing their supply chains to work directly with a smaller number of preferred, mostly large, suppliers capable of meeting their stringent requirements, thereby marginalizing smallholders unable to comply the standards (Maertens and Swinnen, 2009). By contrast, higher standards can be a catalyst for upgrading. Improving production techniques and product quality to meet higher requirements permits participation in high value-added chains. For example, some smallholders in developing countries have been successful in niche markets for organic and fair trade-certified products, differentiating themselves from non-certified producers (van Beuningen and Knorringa, 2009). Over the past decade or so, the "compliance-based model" (Locke et al. , 2009) of governing GVCs through private standards aimed at improving quality, social and environmental outcomes has proven inadequate to address these concerns. With
  • 24. regard to labor conditions, the ineffectiveness of the compliance model has been under intense scrutiny following a series of highly publicized tragic events. Dozens of worker suicides in Foxconn's factories in China since 2010 shed light on horrific conditions that confront those who assembled high-tech products like the iPhone. The latest building collapse in Bangladesh that killed over a thousand garment workers in 2013 illuminates the precarious factory conditions under which garments are manufactured by suppliers for global retail and apparel brands like H & M, Zara and Tesco. In many of such cases, contributing to these undesirable conditions are the buyers' own purchasing and supply chain management practices, such as cost-cutting, shortening lead times and last-minute changes, which often make the supplier unable to observe their labor codes (Barrientos, 2013). The limited impact of the compliance model has led to a search for alternative paths for social upgrading (Gereffi and Luo, 2014). More attention is being given to joint actions by multiple stakeholders to combine compliance monitoring with capability building so that supplier can learn how to address labor issues on their own (O'Rourke, 2006). Moreover, bottom-up approaches highlight the importance of local embeddedness. While developing country firms tend to be portrayed as "standard-takers", they can initiate their own effort to improve working conditions, often collectively within clusters (Lund- Thomsen and Nadvi, 2010). Active roles can be played by workers and labor unions in GVCs, who often are the best monitors on the ground (O'Rourke, 2006) and who have considerable power to disrupt the supply chains in their bargaining with employers (Selwyn, 2013). Finally, in the face of workers' grievances and public criticisms over undesirable labor conditions, governments need to enforce stricter labor laws and regulations and actively police labor abuses. Government actions can go beyond the traditional law- enforcing role and adopt innovative and experimental approaches by collaborating with private and civil actors
  • 25. (Locke, 2013). Different forms of governance can work together to complement each other (Amengual, 2010), and this can lead to "synergistic governance" (Mayer, 2014). To make this happen, one needs to go beyond the factory as the unit of analysis (and intervention) to take into account a broader array of governance forms and public and civil society actors that could complement private GVC governance and global lead firms (Gereffi et al. , 2014). Conclusion Our discussion of the changing dynamics of GVCs in the post- crisis global economy underscores the important yet complex role of GVCs in shaping economic and social outcomes for RP firms and emerging economies. Rising geographic and organizational concentration in many GVCs leads to an uneven distribution of upgrading opportunities that should favor RP firms. Similarly, the rise of emerging economies as new end markets for GVCs and the regionalization of value chains can benefit RP firms. RP firms can play a significant role in reconstructing GVCs by building up regional supply chains and retail networks and South-South value chains. These can provide alternative markets where RP firms complete with global firms on better terms, either with more local knowledge or business models uniquely suited to developing country markets. At the same time, without further upgrading, such competitive advantage may be short-lived or only sustainable at the expense of worsening labor conditions for marginalized workers. However, this article has also challenged some of the current stereotypes about RP firms. They need to be analyzed within the context of contemporary GVCs, not just as the newest variety of "third world multinationals". MNEs from the East Asian NIEs have had a strong influence not only on the export performance of emerging economies, particularly China, but also on their innovation potential. As RP firms become fully integrated into GVCs, their global strategies can be powerfully influenced by their linkages to advanced countries as well as their domestic
  • 26. markets[16]. In terms of new patterns of GVC governance focused on social upgrading, the inability of voluntary corporate codes to address the root causes of poor labor conditions in the factories linked to GVCs has led to the call for joint governance systems built through a cooperation of MNEs, local firms and transnational and local NGOs, labor unions and governments on various levels. It remains to be seen whether such cooperative governance can address a wider array of social development issues beyond workplace and workers' rights. Thus, the conditions under which social value and benefits are likely to be co-created within and across private, public or civil sector (Sinkovics et al. , 2014a) can be one of the topics on which GVC and critical IB scholars can fruitfully collaborate. In such an endeavor, critical IB scholarship could contribute to the GVC approach by providing a deep understanding of MNEs' hierarchical governance, various business strategies beyond supply chain management and internal decision-making and coordination process across different geographies. Corresponding author Joonkoo Lee can be contacted at: [email protected] Notes Global production network (GPN) research has many commonalities with the GVC approach, as both pay close attention to fragmented and dispersed production systems across national borders. Efforts to distinguish the two perspectives highlight the former's relative emphasis on local institutions and embeddedness (Coe et al. , 2008; Henderson et al. , 2002; Hess and Yeung, 2006), while GVC analysis deals more specifically with vertical commercial linkages and the role of power in global supply chains (Bair, 2009; Ponte and Sturgeon, 2014). This paper, however, focuses on the GVC literature to highlight its potential contribution to the critical IB literature. For a comparison of the GPN and GVC literatures, see Sturgeon (2001, 2009) and Neilson et al. (2014). By 2011, Nike's products were made in 930 factories in 50
  • 27. countries, employing more than 1 million workers. However, Nike itself had just 38,000 direct employees, most of whom work in the USA. Nike's $15 billion in total sales included $10.3 billion for footwear and $5 billion for apparel. However, just 73 of Nike's 930 suppliers in 2011 were producing shoes, and most were located in Asia (Locke, 2013, p. 48). This highlights the fact that similar industries in terms of products often have contrasting forms of industrial organization, GVC governance structures and upgrading outcomes, even with the same lead firm. This is true of Nike's buyer-driven footwear and apparel suppliers: offshore footwear factories are relatively large, capital-intensive operations, which Nike was able to monitor much more closely, while garment factories are usually smaller and highly labor-intensive operations, leading to much greater volatility in performance and compliance with Nike's corporate codes of conduct. The biggest car part suppliers (with 2013 revenues in parentheses) include Bosch ($67.5 billion, 2012); Continental ($44.3 billion); Denso ($43.3 billion); Johnson Controls ($42.7 billion) and Magna International ($34.8 billion). Some of the leading car companies they supply include Honda Motor ($119.5 billion), Fiat ($115.3 billion) and BMW ($101 billion) (Foy, 2014). The global top 10 auto parts suppliers account for 60 per cent of total revenues of the world's 100 largest automotive suppliers. Operating margins of the ten largest automotive suppliers are about 4 percentage points higher, on average, than those of the ten biggest carmakers (Foy, 2014). The role of mega suppliers in the automotive value chain is paralleled by the rise of global contract manufacturers in electronics (Sturgeon and Lester, 2004), and large-scale systems integrators in the aircraft and shipbuilding industries (Gereffi et al. , 2013). "Capturing the Gains" is an international research network to examine the relationship between economic and social upgrading in GVCs. The project publications, working papers,
  • 28. policy briefs and other activities are listed at www.capturingthegains.org/ The three main components of the OLI eclectic paradigm are: ownership advantages, locational advantages and internalization advantages. For an updated version of the "late comer" thesis applied to developmental states in East Asia and elsewhere, see the discussion of "compressed development" in Whittaker et al. (2010). Li & Fung has about 15,000 suppliers globally and operates in more than 40 countries (Fung, 2011). A similar argument could be made with respect to the dynamics of "triangle manufacturing" whereby MNEs from the East Asian NIEs played a critical role in extending production in GVCs to a broad range of low-cost locations that included small countries as well as RP economies, thereby creating more flexible sourcing networks that leveraged quota and regional trade agreement constraints and preferences in ways that increased participation by low-income economies, including RPs, in GVCs (Gereffi, 1999). This is perhaps most clearly visible in the global apparel industry; see Morris et al. (2011) on South Africa's links to Lesotho and Swaziland and Bair and Gereffi (2014) on how East Asian production networks in Nicaragua are leveraging features of the Central America Free Trade Agreement (CAFTA) and North American Free Trade Agreement (NAFTA) trade agreements. Similarly, over 40 per cent of the world's apparel exports came from China alone, and the top 5 leading exporting countries accounted for 60 per cent of world export value in 2010 (Bernhardt, 2013). Figures on mobile phone sales (2012) and smartphone OS (2012, 4Q) are from Gartner (2013b). Smartphone sales figures (2013, 2Q) are from Gartner (2013a). Market shares in contract manufacturing (2010) are from NIPA (2011). US-based Apple is estimated to capture between one-third and one-half of an iPod's retail price; Asian firms, like Toshiba
  • 29. from Japan and Samsung from South Korea, capture the largest manufacturing shares as profits from high-value components, such as the hard-disk drive, display and memory; and the assembly and testing activities by Chinese workers get just 2 per cent of the final product price (Timmer et al. , 2014, p. 99). Private standards can be mandatory in a de facto sense if complying with them is a precondition for participation in the GVC. Public governance involves rules and regulations set by various levels of governments in nation-states and supra-national entities like the International Labor Organization. Social governance is driven by civil society actors such as non- governmental organizations (NGOs) and labor unions. It includes codes of conduct initiated by NGOs and multi- stakeholder initiatives, such as Ethical Trade Initiative. This is the case of India's role in the dynamic offshore services GVC, which began with "body shopping" in the US. economy in the late 1990s in response to the perceived need to rewrite massive amounts of software code to avert a potential Y2K crisis, and has evolved to the point where India has some of the world's leading offshore services MNEs, such as Infosys, Wipro and Tata Consultancy Services, but still oriented to global clients (Fernandez-Stark et al. , 2011). References References Amengual, M. ( 2010 ), " Complementary labor regulation: the uncoordinated combination of state and private regulators in the Dominican Republic ",World Development , Vol. 38 No. 3, pp. 405 - 414 . Appelbaum, R.P. ( 2008 ), " Giant transnational contractors in East Asia: emergent trends in global supply chains ",Competition & Change , Vol. 12 No. 1, pp. 69 - 87 . Bair, J. ( 2005 ), " Global capitalism and commodity chains: looking back, going forward ",Competition & Change , Vol. 9 No. 2, pp. 153 - 180 . Bair, J. ( 2009 ), " Global commodity chains: genealogy and
  • 30. review ", in Bair, J. (Ed.),Frontiers of Commodity Chain Research , Stanford University Press, Stanford, CA, pp. 1 - 34 . Bair, J. and Gereffi, G. ( 2001 ), " Local clusters in global chains: the causes and consequences of export dynamism in Torreon's blue jeans industry ",World Development , Vol. 29 No. 11, pp. 1885 - 1903 . Bair, J. and Gereffi, G. ( 2014 ), " Towards better work in Central America: Nicaragua and the CAFTA Context ", in Rossi, A., Luinstra, A. and Pickles, J. (Eds),Towards Better Work: Understanding Labour in Apparel Global Value Chains , Palgrave Macmillan, Houndmills, pp. 251 - 275 . Balfour, F. and Culpan, T. ( 2010 ), " The man who makes your iPhone ", available at: www.businessweek.com/magazine/content/10_38/b41950584234 79.htm Barrientos, S. ( 2013 ), " Corporate purchasing practices in global production networks: a socially contested terrain ",Geoforum , Vol. 44, pp. 44 - 51 . Barrientos, S., Gereffi, G. and Nathan, D. ( 2012 ), " Economic and social upgrading in global value chains: emerging trends and pressures ", Capturing the Gains Summit Briefing, University of Manchester, available at: www.capturingthegains.org/pdf/CTG-GVC.pdf Barrientos, S., Gereffi, G. and Rossi, A. ( 2011 ), " Economic and social upgrading in global production networks: a new paradigm for a changing world ",International Labour Review , Vol. 150 Nos 3/4, pp. 319 - 340 . Barrientos, S. and Visser, M. ( 2012 ), " South African horticulture: opportunities and challenges for economic and social upgrading in value chains ", Capturing the Gains Working Paper 2012/12, University of Manchester, available at: www.capturingthegains.org/publications/workingpapers/wp_201 212.htm Bazan, L. and Navas-Alemán, L. ( 2004 ), " The underground revolution in the Sinos Valley: a comparison of upgrading in global and national value chains ", in Schmitz, H. (Ed.),Local
  • 31. Enterprises in the Global Economy: Issues of Governance and Upgrading , Elgar, Cheltenham, pp. 110 - 139 . Bernhardt, T. ( 2013 ), " Developing countries in the global apparel value chain: a tale of upgrading and downgrading experiences ", Capturing the Gains Working Paper 2013/22, available at: www.capturingthegains.org/publications/workingpapers/wp_201 322.htm Borrus, M.G., Ernst, D. and Haggard, S. ( 2000 ),International Production Networks in Asia: Rivalry or Riches? Routledge, London . Brandt, L. and Thun, E. ( 2011 ), " Going mobile in China: shifting value chains and upgrading in the mobile telecom sector ",International Journal of Technological Learning, Innovation and Development , Vol. 4 Nos 1/3, pp. 148 - 180 . Buckley, P.J. ( 2009 ), " The impact of the global factory on economic development ",Journal of World Business , Vol. 44 No. 2, pp. 131 - 143 . Buckley, P.J. and Ghauri, P.N. ( 2004 ), " Globalisation, economic geography and the strategy of multinational enterprises ",Journal of International Business Studies , Vol. 35 No. 2, pp. 81 - 98 . Cattaneo, O., Gereffi, G. and Staritz, C. ( 2010 ),Global Value Chains in a Postcrisis World: A Development Perspective , World Bank, Washington, DC . Chan, J., Pun, N. and Selden, M. ( 2013 ), " The politics of global production: Apple, Foxconn and China's new working class ",New Technology, Work and Employment , Vol. 28 No. 2, pp. 100 - 115 . Clark, N., Chataway, J., Hanlin, R., Kale, D., Kaplinsky, R., Muraguri, L., Papaioannou, T., Robbins, P. and Wamae, W. ( 2009 ), " Below the radar: what does innovation in the Asian driver economies have to offer other low income economies ", Innogen Working Paper No. 69, Milton Keynes, available at: http://oro.open.ac.uk/15241 / Coe, N.M., Dicken, P. and Hess, M. ( 2008 ), " Global
  • 32. production networks: realizing the potential ",Journal of Economic Geography , Vol. 8 No. 3, pp. 271 - 295 . De Marchi, V., Di Maria, E. and Ponte, S. ( 2014 ), " Multinational firms and the management of global networks: insights from global value chain studies ", in Pedersen, T., Venzin, M., Devinney, T.M. and Tihanyi, L. (Eds),Orchestration of the Global Network Organization (Advances in International Management) , Emerald, Bingley, Vol. 27, pp. 463 - 486 . Dedrick, J., Kraemer, K.L. and Linden, G. ( 2011 ), " The distribution of value in the mobile phone supply chain ",Telecommunications Policy , Vol. 35 No. 6, pp. 505 - 521 . Donaghu, M.T. and Barff, R. ( 1990 ), " Nike just did it: international subcontracting and flexibility in athletic footwear production ",Regional Studies , Vol. 24 No. 6, pp. 537 - 552 . Evers, B., Opondo, M., Barrientos, S., Krishnan, A., Amoding, F. and Ndlovu, L. ( 2014 ), " Global and regional supermarkets: implications for producers and workers in Kenyan and Ugandan horticulture ", Capturing the Gains Working Paper 2014/39, available at: www.capturingthegains.org/publications/workingpapers/wp_201 212.htm Farole, T. and Winkler, D. ( 2014 ),Making Foreign Direct Investment Work for Sub-Saharan Africa: Local Spillovers and Competitiveness in Global Value Chains , World Bank Publications, Washington, DC . Fernandez-Stark, K., Bamber, P. and Gereffi, G. ( 2011 ), " The offshore services value chain: upgrading trajectories in developing countries ",International Journal of Technological Learning, Innovation and Development , Vol. 4 Nos 1/3, pp. 206 - 234 . Fold, N. ( 2002 ), " Lead firms and competition in 'bi-polar' commodity chains: grinders and branders in the global cocoa- chocolate industry ",Journal of Agrarian Change , Vol. 2 No. 2, pp. 228 - 247 . Foy, H. ( 2014 ), " Age of mega supplier heralds danger for carmakers ",Financial Times , available at:
  • 33. www.ft.com/intl/cms/s/0/50c272c4-dce9-11e3-ba13- 00144feabdc0.html #slide0 Fung, V. ( 2011 ), " Global supply chains - past developments, emerging trends ", available at: www.fungglobalinstitute.org/en/global-supply-chains- %E2%80%93-past-developments-emerging-trends Gartner . ( 2013a ), " Gartner says smartphone sales grew 46.5 per cent in second quarter of 2013 and exceeded feature phone sales for first time ", available at: www.gartner.com/newsroom/id/2573415 Gartner . ( 2013b ), " Gartner says worldwide mobile phone sales declined 1.7 per cent in 2012 ", available at: www.gartner.com/newsroom/id/2335616 Gereffi, G. ( 1994 ), " The organization of buyer-driven global commodity chains: how US retailers shape overseas production networks ", in Gereffi, G. and Korzeniewicz, M. (Eds),Commodity Chains and Global Capitalism , Greenwood Press, Westport, CT, pp. 95 - 122 . Gereffi, G. ( 1996 ), " Commodity chains and regional divisions of labor in East Asia ",Journal of Asian Business , Vol. 12 No. 1, pp. 75 - 112 . Gereffi, G. ( 1999 ), " International trade and industrial upgrading in the apparel commodity chains ",Journal of International Economics , Vol. 48 No. 1, pp. 37 - 70 . Gereffi, G. ( 2009 ), " Development models and industrial upgrading in China and Mexico ",European Sociological Review , Vol. 25 No. 1, pp. 37 - 51 . Gereffi, G. ( 2014 ), " Global value chains in a post-Washington Consensus world ",Review of International Political Economy , Vol. 21 No. 1, pp. 9 - 37 . Gereffi, G., Brun, L., Stokes, S. and Guinn, A. ( 2013 ), " The NSPS shipbuilding value chain ", available at: www.cggc.duke.edu/pdfs/NSPS_GVC_Analysis_Jan2013_01282 013.pdf Gereffi, G. and Fernandez-Stark, K. ( 2011 ), " Global value chain analysis: a primer ", Center on Globalization, Governance
  • 34. & Competitiveness, Durham, NC, available at: www.cggc.duke.edu/pdfs/2011-05- 31_GVC_analysis_a_primer.pdf Gereffi, G. and Kaplinsky, R. ( 2001 ),The Value of Value Chains: Spreading the Gains from Globalisation , Institute of Development Studies, Brighton . Gereffi, G. and Korzeniewicz, M. ( 1994 ),Commodity Chains and Global Capitalism , Greenwood Press, Westport, CT . Gereffi, G. and Lee, J. ( 2012 ), " Why the world suddenly cares about global supply chains ",Journal of Supply Chain Management , Vol. 48 No. 3, pp. 24 - 32 . Gereffi, G. and Luo, X. ( 2014 ), " Risks and opportunities of participation in global value chains ", Policy Research Working Paper 6847, World Bank, Washington, DC . Gereffi, G., Regini, M. and Sabel, C.F. ( 2014 ), " On Richard M. Locke, the promise and limits of private power: promoting labor standards in a global economy, New York, Cambridge University Press, 2013 ",Socio-Economic Review , Vol. 12 No. 1, pp. 219 - 235 . Gereffi, G. and Sturgeon, T.J. ( 2013 ), " Global value chain- oriented industrial policy: the role of emerging economies ", in Elms, D.K. and Low, P. (Eds),Global Value Chains in a Changing World , World Trade Organization, Fung Global Institute and Temasek Foundation Centre for Trade & Negotiations, Geneva, pp. 329 - 360 . Gereffi, G., Humphrey, J. and Sturgeon, T. ( 2005 ), " The governance of global value chains ",Review of International Political Economy , Vol. 12 No. 1, pp. 78 - 104 . Ghauri, P.N. and Yamin, M. ( 2009 ), " Revisiting the impact of multinational enterprises on economic development ",Journal of World Business , Vol. 44 No. 2, pp. 105 - 107 . Gibbon, P. and Ponte, S. ( 2008 ), " Global value chains: from governance to governmentality? ",Economy and Society , Vol. 37 No. 3, pp. 365 - 392 . Gifford, B., Kestler, A. and Anand, S. ( 2010 ), " Building local legitimacy into corporate social responsibility: gold mining
  • 35. firms in developing nations ",Journal of World Business , Vol. 45 No. 3, pp. 304 - 311 . Giuliani, E., Pietrobelli, C. and Rabellotti, R. ( 2005 ), " Upgrading in global value chains: lessons from Latin American clusters ",World Development , Vol. 33 No. 4, pp. 549 - 573 . Grimes, S. and Sun, Y. ( 2014 ), " Implications of China's on- going dependence on foreign technology ",Geoforum , Vol. 54, pp. 59 - 69 . Hamilton, G.G. and Gereffi, G. ( 2009 ), " Global commodity chains, market makers, and the rise of demand-responsive economies ", in Bair, J. (Ed.),Frontiers of Commodity Chain Research , Stanford University Press, Stanford, CA, pp. 136 - 161 . Hamilton, G.G., Senauer, B. and Petrovic, M. ( 2011 ),The Market Makers: How Retailers Are Reshaping the Global Economy , Oxford University Press, Oxford, New York, NY . Henderson, J., Dicken, P., Hess, M., Coe, N. and Yeung, H.W.C. ( 2002 ), " Global production networks and the analysis of economic development ",Review of International Political Economy , Vol. 9 No. 3, pp. 436 - 464 . Hess, M. and Yeung, H.W.-C. ( 2006 ), " Whither global production networks in economic geography? Past, present, and future ",Environment and Planning A , Vol. 38 No. 7, pp. 1193 - 1204 . Humphrey, J. ( 2006 ), " Policy implications of trends in agribusiness value chains ",European Journal of Development Research , Vol. 18 No. 4, pp. 572 - 592 . Humphrey, J. and Schmitz, H. ( 2002 ), " How does insertion in global value chains affect upgrading in industrial clusters? ",Regional Studies , Vol. 36 No. 9, pp. 1017 - 1027 . Islam, M.S. ( 2008 ), " From pond to plate: towards a twin- driven commodity chain in Bangladesh shrimp aquaculture ",Food Policy , Vol. 33 No. 3, pp. 209 - 223 . Jiang, X. and Milberg, W. ( 2013 ), " Capturing the jobs from globalisation: trade and employment in global value chains ", Capturing the Gains Working Paper 2013/30, University of
  • 36. Manchester, available at: www.capturingthegains.org/publications/workingpapers/wp_201 330.htm Johanson, J. and Vahlne, J.E. ( 2009 ), " The Uppsala internationalization process model revisited: from liability of foreignness to liability of outsidership ",Journal of International Business Studies , Vol. 40 No. 9, pp. 1411 - 1431 . Kaplinsky, R., Terheggen, A. and Tijaja, J. ( 2011 ), " China as a final market: the Gabon timber and Thai cassava value chains ",World Development , Vol. 39 No. 7, pp. 1177 - 1190 . Kawakami, M. ( 2011 ), " Inter-firm dynamics of notebook PC value chains and the rise of Taiwanese original design manufacturing firms ", in Kawakami, M. and Sturgeon, T. (Eds),The Dynamics of Local Learning in Global Value Chains: Experiences from East Asia , Palgrave Macmillan, Basingstoke, pp. 16 - 42 . Lamy, P. ( 2013 ), " Global value chains, interdependence, and the future of trade ", available at: www.voxeu.org/article/global-value-chains-interdependence- and-future-trade Lee, J. ( 2010 ), " Global commodity chains and global value chains ", in Denemark, R.A. (Ed.),The International Studies Encyclopedia , Wiley-Blackwell, Oxford, pp. 2987 - 3006 . Lee, J.R. and Chen, J.S. ( 2000 ), " Dynamic synergy creation with multiple business activities: toward a competence-based growth model for contract manufacturers ",Advances in Applied Business Strategy , Vol. 6A, pp. 209 - 228 . Lee, J. and Gereffi, G. ( 2013 ), " The co-evolution of concentration in mobile phone global value chains and its impact on social upgrading in developing countries ", Capturing the Gains Working Paper 2013/25, available at: www.capturingthegains.org/publications/workingpapers/wp_201 325.htm Lee, J., Gereffi, G. and Barrientos, S. ( 2011 ), " Global value chains, upgrading and poverty reduction ", Capturing the Gains Briefing Note No. 3, available at:
  • 37. www.capturingthegains.org/pdf/ctg_briefing_note_3.pdf Lee, J., Gereffi, G. and Beauvais, J. ( 2012 ), " Global value chains and agrifood standards: challenges and possibilities for smallholders in developing countries ",Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences of the United States of America , Vol. 191 No. 31, pp. 12326 - 12331 . Locke, R.M. ( 2013 ),The Promise and Limits of Private Power: Promoting Labor Standards in a Global Economy , Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, NY . Locke, R., Amengual, M. and Mangla, A. ( 2009 ), " Virtue out of necessity? Compliance, commitment, and the improvement of labor conditions in global supply chains ",Politics & Society , Vol. 37 No. 3, pp. 319 - 351 . Lund-Thomsen, P. and Nadvi, K. ( 2010 ), " Clusters, chains and compliance: corporate social responsibility and governance in football manufacturing in South Asia ",Journal of Business Ethics , Vol. 93 No. 2, pp. 201 - 222 . Luo, Y. and Tung, R.L. ( 2007 ), " International expansion of emerging market enterprises: a springboard perspective ",Journal of International Business Studies , Vol. 38 No. 4, pp. 481 - 498 . Maertens, M. and Swinnen, J.F.M. ( 2009 ), " Trade, standards, and poverty: evidence from Senegal ",World Development , Vol. 37 No. 1, pp. 161 - 178 . Mayer, F. ( 2014 ), " Leveraging private governance for public purpose: business, civil society and the state in labour regulation ", in Payne, A. and Philips, N. (Eds),Handbook on the International Political Economy of Governance , Edward Elgar, Cheltenham, pp. 344 - 360 . Mayer, F. and Gereffi, G. ( 2010 ), " Regulation and economic globalization: prospects and limits of private governance ",Business and Politics , Vol. 12 No. 3 . Meyer, K.E. ( 2004 ), " Perspectives on multinational enterprises in emerging economies ",Journal of International Business Studies , Vol. 35 No. 4, pp. 259 - 276 . Morris, M., Staritz, C. and Barnes, J. ( 2011 ), " Value chain
  • 38. dynamics, local embeddedness, and upgrading in the clothing sectors of Lesotho and Swaziland ",International Journal of Technological Learning, Innovation and Development , Vol. 4 Nos 1/3, pp. 96 - 119 . Nadvi, K. ( 2014 ), " 'Rising powers' and labour and environmental standards ",Oxford Development Studies , Vol. 42 No. 2, pp. 137 - 150 . Neilson, J., Pritchard, B. and Yeung, H.W.C. ( 2014 ), " Global value chains and global production networks in the changing international political economy: an introduction ",Review of International Political Economy , Vol. 21 No. 1, pp. 1 - 8 . NIPA ( 2011 ),The Rise of EMS/ODM Industry and Its Implications , National IT Industry Promotion Agency, Seoul . Oetzel, J. and Doh, J.P. ( 2009 ), " MNEs and development: a review and reconceptualization ",Journal of World Business , Vol. 44 No. 2, pp. 108 - 120 . Oleniacz, L. ( 2014 ), " Lenovo North America president: PC Plus strategy is paying off ",Durham Morning Herald . O'Rourke, D. ( 2006 ), " Multi-stakeholder regulation: privatizing or socializing global labor standards? ",World Development , Vol. 34 No. 5, pp. 899 - 918 . Ponte, S. and Gibbon, P. ( 2005 ), " Quality standards, conventions and the governance of global value chains ",Economy and Society , Vol. 34 No. 1, pp. 1 - 31 . Ponte, S. and Sturgeon, T. ( 2014 ), " Explaining governance in global value chains: a modular theory-building effort ",Review of International Political Economy , Vol. 21 No. 1, pp. 195 - 223 . Sarkar, S., Mehta, B.S. and Nathan, D. ( 2013 ), " How social upgrading drives economic upgrading by Indian IT majors: the case of telecom IT services ", Capturing the Gains Working Paper 2013/27, University of Manchester, available at: www.capturingthegains.org/publications/workingpapers/wp_201 327.htm Schmitz, H. ( 2004 ),Local Enterprises in the Global Economy: Issues of Governance and Upgrading , Edward Elgar,
  • 39. Cheltenham . Selwyn, B. ( 2013 ), " Social upgrading and labour in global production networks: a critique and an alternative conception ",Competition & Change , Vol. 17 No. 1, pp. 75 - 90 . Sinkovics, N., Sinkovics, R.R. and Yamin, M. ( 2014a ), " The role of social value creation in business model formulation at the bottom of the pyramid - implications for MNEs? ",International Business Review , Vol. 23 No. 4, pp. 692 - 707 . Sinkovics, R.R. and Yamin, M. ( 2012 ), " Special issue on rising power firms and FDI: the challenge of economic development ",Critical Perspectives on International Business , Vol. 8 No. 4 . Sinkovics, R.R., Yamin, M., Nadvi, K. and Zhang, Y.Z. ( 2014b ), " Rising powers from emerging markets - the changing face of international business ",International Business Review , Vol. 23 No. 4, pp. 675 - 679 . Staritz, C., Gereffi, G. and Cattaneo, O. ( 2011 ), " Editorial ",International Journal of Technological Learning, Innovation and Development , Vol. 4 Nos 1/3, pp. 1 - 12 . Sturgeon, T.J. ( 2001 ), " How do we define value chains and production networks? ",IDS Bulletin , Vol. 32 No. 3, pp. 9 - 18 . Sturgeon, T.J. ( 2009 ), " From commodity chains to value chains: interdisciplinary theory building in an age of globalization ", in Bair, J. (Ed.),Frontiers of Commodity Chain Research , Stanford University Press, Stanford, CA, pp. 110 - 135 . Sturgeon, T.J. and Lester, R.K. ( 2004 ), " The new global supply-base: new challenges for local suppliers in East Asia ", in Yusuf, S., Altaf, M.A. and Nabeshima, K. (Eds),Global Production Networking and Technological Change in East Asia , Oxford University Press, Oxford, pp. 35 - 87 . Timmer, M.P., Erumban, A.A., Los, B., Stehrer, R. and de Vries, G.J. ( 2014 ), " Slicing up global value chains ",Journal of Economic Perspectives , Vol. 28 No. 2, pp. 99 - 118 . UNCTAD ( 2013 ), " Global value chains and development: investment and value added trade in the global economy ",
  • 40. United Nations Conference on Trade and Development, Geneva, available at: http://unctad.org/en/publicationslibrary/diae2013d1_en.pdf van Beuningen, C. and Knorringa, P. ( 2009 ),Inclusive Improvement: Standards and Smallholders - Taking Stock and Moving On , Hivos, The Hague . Wadhwa, V. ( 2013 ), " A lesson from Chile ",Wall Street Journal , available at: http://blogs.wsj.com/accelerators/2013/08/26/vivek-wadhwa-a- lesson-from-chile / Whittaker, D., Zhu, T., Sturgeon, T., Tsai, M. and Okita, T. ( 2010 ), " Compressed development ",Studies in Comparative International Development , Vol. 45 No. 4, pp. 439 - 467 . Williamson, O. ( 1985 ),The Economic Institutions of Capitalism: Firms, Markets, Relational Contracting , Free Press, New York, NY . WTO ( 2011 ),International Trade Statistics 2011 , World Trade Organization, Geneva . WTO and IDE-JETRO ( 2011 ), " Trade patterns and global value chains in East Asia: from trade in goods to trade in tasks ", World Trade Organization and Institute of Developing Economies, Geneva and Tokyo, available at: www.wto.org/english/res_e/publications_e/stat_tradepat_globva lchains_e.htm Yamin, M. and Sinkovics, R.R. ( 2009 ), " Infrastructure or foreign direct investment? An examination of the implications of MNE strategy for economic development ",Journal of World Business , Vol. 44 No. 2, pp. 144 - 157 . AuthorAffiliation Joonkoo Lee School of Business, Hanyang University, Seoul, South Korea Gary Gereffi Department of Sociology, Duke University, Durham, North Carolina, USA Word count: 11271 Show less You have requested "on-the-fly" machine translation of selected
  • 41. content from our databases. This functionality is provided solely for your convenience and is in no way intended to replace human translation. Show full disclaimer Neither ProQuest nor its licensors make any representations or warranties with respect to the translations. The translations are automatically generated "AS IS" and "AS AVAILABLE" and are not retained in our systems. PROQUEST AND ITS LICENSORS SPECIFICALLY DISCLAIM ANY AND ALL EXPRESS OR IMPLIED WARRANTIES, INCLUDING WITHOUT LIMITATION, ANY WARRANTIES FOR AVAILABILITY, ACCURACY, TIMELINESS, COMPLETENESS, NON-INFRINGMENT, MERCHANTABILITY OR FITNESS FOR A PARTICULAR PURPOSE. Your use of the translations is subject to all use restrictions contained in your Electronic Products License Agreement and by using the translation functionality you agree to forgo any and all claims against ProQuest or its licensors for your use of the translation functionality and any output derived there from. Hide full disclaimer Translations powered by LEC. Translations powered by LEC. © Emerald Group Publishing Limited 2015 English Arabic BRQ Business Research Quarterly (2017) 20, 137---150 www.elsevier.es/brq BRQBusiness ResearchQuarterly REVIEW ESSAY
  • 42. Global value chain configuration: A review and research agenda Virginia Hernándeza,∗ , Torben Pedersenb a University Carlos III of Madrid, Business Management Division, C/ Madrid, 126, 28903 Getafe, Madrid, Spain b Bocconi University, Department of Management and Technology, Via Roentgen 1, 20136 Milan, Italy Received 28 November 2015; accepted 29 November 2016 Available online 23 January 2017 JEL CLASSIFICATION M16 KEYWORDS Literature review; Global value chain; International business; GVC configuration Abstract This paper reviews the literature on global value chain configuration, providing an overview of this topic. Specifically, we review the literature focusing on the concept of the global value chain and its activities, the decisions involved in its configuration, such as location, the governance modes chosen and the different ways of coordinating them. We also examine the outcomes of a global value chain configuration in terms of performance and upgrading. Our aim is to review the state of the art of these issues,
  • 43. identify research gaps and suggest new lines for future research that would advance our understanding of how firms are implementing new ways of organizing and managing activities on a global scale. © 2016 ACEDE. Published by Elsevier España, S.L.U. This is an open access article under the CC BY-NC-ND license (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by- nc-nd/4.0/). Introduction A vast amount of research has focused on different configu- rational aspects of firms’ activities worldwide. Specifically, an important part of the literature has focused on explain- ing the reasons and effects of locating individual activities in foreign countries (Lewin et al., 2009; Martínez-Noya and García-Canal, 2011; Rodríguez and Nieto, 2016; Schmeisser, 2013). Nevertheless, research has increasingly broadened this perspective to go beyond the analysis of specific ∗ Corresponding author. E-mail addresses: [email protected] (V. Hernández), [email protected] (T. Pedersen). activities and encompass the whole value chain. This has prompted the emergence of several lines of research examining different aspects of the global value chain configuration, including: governance types (Buckley and Strange, 2015; Gereffi et al., 2005), levels of disaggregation (Asmussen et al., 2007; Beugelsdijk et al., 2009),
  • 44. geographic scope (Los et al., 2015; Mudambi and Puck, 2016), and the upgrading processes of the firms involved (De Marchi et al., 2013; Humphrey and Schmitz, 2002; Lema et al., 2015). Recent studies have reviewed the literature that focuses on the different theoretical perspectives in global supply chain management (Connelly et al., 2013). However, a com- prehensive review of the literature dealing with the state of the art of the global value chain configuration has not yet been carried out. Firms are constantly taking decisions http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.brq.2016.11.001 2340-9436/© 2016 ACEDE. Published by Elsevier España, S.L.U. This is an open access article under the CC BY-NC-ND license (http:// creativecommons.org/licenses/by-nc-nd/4.0/). dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.brq.2016.11.001 http://www.elsevier.es/brq http://crossmark.crossref.org/dialog/?doi=10.1016/j.brq.2016.11 .001&domain=pdf http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by-nc-nd/4.0/ http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by-nc-nd/4.0/ http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by-nc-nd/4.0/ http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by-nc-nd/4.0/ http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by-nc-nd/4.0/ http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by-nc-nd/4.0/ http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by-nc-nd/4.0/ http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by-nc-nd/4.0/ http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by-nc-nd/4.0/ http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by-nc-nd/4.0/ mailto:[email protected]
  • 45. mailto:[email protected] dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.brq.2016.11.001 http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by-nc-nd/4.0/ http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by-nc-nd/4.0/ http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by-nc-nd/4.0/ http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by-nc-nd/4.0/ http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by-nc-nd/4.0/ http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by-nc-nd/4.0/ http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by-nc-nd/4.0/ http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by-nc-nd/4.0/ http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by-nc-nd/4.0/ http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by-nc-nd/4.0/ 138 V. Hernández, T. Pedersen Governance Location Coordination Performance Upgrading The global valu e chain configu ration Concept and activiti es Dec isions Implication s Figure 1 Topics covered in this literature review. in an interconnected world that not only affect their struc- tures, capabilities and results, but also those of the other agents they interact with. It is thus necessary to clearly identify the decisions involved in a global value chain con- figuration that have been already examined and, from that, the aspects that remain unexplored. The purpose of this article is therefore to review the literature on global value chain configurations in order to systematize it and indicate avenues for future research (see Fig. 1). The study contributes to global value chain literature in
  • 46. several ways. We believe that, traditionally, research has been focused on specific topics involved in its configuration such as decisions on location, governance and coordination. A review examining all of them allows us to better under- stand not only the characteristics of each decision but also the interdependencies between them. Additionally, it allows us to observe the complexity of a global value chain con- figuration that may be constantly evolving due to changes in countries, industries and firms. All in all, it allows us to identify the topics that remain unexplored and present those lines of research that, in our view, remain unanswered. The rest of the paper is structured as follows. First, we explain the global value chain concept and the different activities composing it. Secondly, we describe how the liter- ature has classified the different value chain configurations and the key decisions in designing the global value chain, namely governance, geographical scope and coordination of activities. Thirdly, we explore the outcomes related to global value chain configurations in terms of performance and upgrading. Finally, we suggest future lines of research and establish the conclusions that can be drawn from the study. Global value chains: concept and activities Over the years, scholars have analyzed different termi- nology to define how firms organize activities such as commodity chains (Gereffi and Korzeniewicz, 1994;
  • 47. Selwyn, 2015), supply chains (Al-Mudimigh et al., 2004; Connelly et al., 2013; Priem and Swink, 2012), value networks (de Reuver and Bouwman, 2012; Stabell and Fjeldstad, 1998), etc., depending on the specific relationships that have emerged among firms and other agents within it (Gereffi et al., 2001). Commodity chains focus on exam- ining industries and the authority and power relationships that have emerged within them to explain the role of a leading firm (Mahutga, 2012) --- the firm which shapes, con- trols, coordinates and distributes the value along the chain (Azmeh and Nadvi, 2014). A distinction has thus been made between buyer-driven commodity chains --- in which the leading corporation plays a central role as merchandiser and makes sure that all pieces of the business come together --- and producer-driven commodity chains --- in which the leading corporation plays a central role in production activ- ities (Gereffi and Korzeniewicz, 1994). Other scholars have focused on the analysis of supply chains, where the supply chain concept explains the firms’ relationships with suppli- ers and customers to deliver product or services at less cost (Christopher, 2005). The value chain concept goes a step further, and explains that entities may be connected and create a value which is a source of competitive advantage (Al-Mudimigh et al., 2004; Stabell and Fjeldstad, 1998). This latter concept also takes into account the customers in a privileged position (Cox, 1999), understanding their needs and offering them value (Di Domenico et al., 2007), by
  • 48. exam- ining value creation and its capture (Gereffi and Lee, 2012). Moreover, when the value chain involves a constellation of organizational arrangements and firms that are intercon- nected through a global network, the global value chain concept emerges (De Marchi et al., 2014; Giroud and Mirza, 2015; Mudambi and Puck, 2016). Hence, the global value chain is defined as ‘‘the full range of activities that firms and workers perform to bring a product from its concep- tion to end use and beyond’’, that are carried out on a global scale and that can be undertaken by one or more firms (Gereffi and Fernandez-Stark, 2011, p. 4). Specifically, some scholars point toward a new system called the ‘‘global factory’’ (Buckley, 2011; Buckley and Ghauri, 2004), which entails the organization of activities in a complex configura- tion. This system describes how firms may reduce location and transaction costs by orchestrating the global value chain in such a way that all activities are linked by international flows of intermediate products that the MNC controls but does not necessarily own, and where knowledge is increas- ingly internalized (Buckley and Strange, 2015). One of the crucial aspects of building an overview of global value chain configuration is therefore an examina- tion of the activities involved, which can be grouped based on different criteria (see Table 1). Porter (1991) differ-
  • 49. entiates primary activities --- those related to producing, delivering and marketing the product or service---from sup- port activities. The latter are either related to creating and sourcing inputs or else to those factors that are integral to the firm and facilitate the work of primary activities, such as ensuring efficiency and effectiveness (Priem and Swink, 2012; Tansuchat et al., 2016). It is also possible to distin- guish between upstream and downstream activities, based on their closeness to the exploitation of raw materials or to the manufacturing and customization of the product, respectively (Nicovich et al., 2007; Pananond, 2013; Singer and Donoso, 2008; Verbeke et al., 2016). Mudambi (2008) Global value chain configuration: A review and research agenda 139 Table 1 Classification of activities in the value chain. Criteria Classification Description Studies Degree of involvement in the production process Primary activities Those including creation, production, logistics, marketing and customer service. Porter, 1991; Priem and Swink, 2012; Tansuchat et al., 2016 Support activities Those related to procurement,
  • 50. technology development, human resource management, and general infrastructure. Function in the value chain Upstream activities Those close to the exploitation of natural resources and raw materials or those related to design, basic and applied research and the commercialization of creative endeavors. Mudambi, 2008; Mudambi and Puck, 2016; Nicovich et al., 2007; Pananond, 2013; Singer and Donoso, 2008; Verbeke et al., 2016 Middle-end activities Those related to manufacturing and logistics. Downstream activities Those close to the ultimate consumer that add value to the product by manufacturing or customization. Those related to marketing, advertising, brand management, after-sales services, etc. Potential for competence creation
  • 51. Exploration-related activities Those that create new areas of competence by extending the firm’s capabilities and involving new combinations of resources. Cantwell and Mudambi, 2005; Cantwell and Piscitello, 2015; Ha and Giroud, 2015 Exploitation-related activities Those based on the existing firm’s capabilities. Potential for being a source of competitive advantage Core activities Activities which are distinctive and crucial for competitive advantage. Espino-Rodríguez and Rodríguez-Díaz, 2014; Gilley and Rasheed, 2000; Linares-Navarro et al., 2014; McIvor, 2000; Quinn, 1999 Essential activities Those activities which are complementary and important for competitive advantage.
  • 52. Non-core activities Those activities that give low added value to the firm. adds a third type called middle-end activities. Under this last approach, upstream activities are those that involve design and research, both basic and applied, and the com- mercialization of creative endeavors; downstream activities typically comprise marketing, advertising, brand manage- ment, and after-sales services; and middle-end activities are related to manufacturing, standardized service delivery and other repetitious processes in which commercialized proto- types are implemented on a mass scale. Activities may also be divided by distinguishing between those related to explo- ration from those related to exploitation, based on whether they are competence-creating activities --- such as those that are technologically advanced --- or competence-exploiting activities --- such as those that imply local adaptation while deploying existing technologies (Cantwell and Mudambi, 2005; Cantwell and Piscitello, 2015; Ha and Giroud, 2015). Other classifications take into account activities’ impor- tance in terms of the firm’s competitive advantage and distinguish between core and non-core activities (Espino- Rodríguez and Rodríguez-Díaz, 2014; Gilley and Rasheed, 2000; McIvor, 2000) or between core, essential and non- core activities (Contractor et al., 2010; Quinn, 1999; Linares- Navarro et al., 2014). According to this latter view, core activities are those with high added-value, which are dis- tinctive and crucial for competitive advantage, and are
  • 53. supposed to be the ones the firm performs better than any other company; essential activities are those needed for sus- taining profitable operations that are complementary and important for competitive advantage; and non-core activi- ties are those that can easily be outsourced. 140 V. Hernández, T. Pedersen How firms configure this complex system of activities requires an analysis of different decisions, and we will exam- ine these in the following sections. Configuring a global value chain The configuration of a global value chain has evolved in recent decades. Initially, activities were defined in large blocks ranging from low-end manufacturing and service activities to R&D, design and engineering. More recently, some scholars have pointed out that the value chain can no longer be seen as a set of traditional activities, as firms have engaged in a process of fine-slicing activities (Beugelsdijk et al., 2009; Contractor et al., 2010; Mudambi, 2008; Mudambi and Puck, 2016). This process of generating finer modules has several implications. On the one hand, firms have improved their learning about their own systems or about organizing activities in new ways and specifying connections among them; on the other, it has allowed firms to redefine their core and non-core activities, keeping the
  • 54. true core activities in-house and allocating more resources, time and effort to those activities they do best (Gilley and Rasheed, 2000; Linares-Navarro et al., 2014). It implies a process of modularization that takes large groups of activi- ties --- such as those related to R&D, production or marketing --- and disaggregates them into sub-activities (Contractor et al., 2010). Indeed, specialization may give some firms the opportunity to develop superior capabilities that give them a competitive advantage (Jacobides and Winter, 2005). Firms thus have to decide: how to organize their activities --- keep them in house, go to the market or use mixed modes such as alliances with other firms (Castañer et al., 2014; Gereffi et al., 2005), where to locate these activities (Jensen and Pedersen, 2011; Los et al., 2015; Mudambi and Puck, 2016), and how to coordinate them globally (Beugelsdijk et al., 2009; Hansen et al., 2009). Moreover, firms have to take into account that these choices may change and evolve over time depending on the circumstances, and must there- fore review them continuously (Buckley, 2011; Buckley and Ghauri, 2004). Governance structures of the global value chain Governance refers to ‘‘authority and power relation- ships that determine how financial, material, and human resources are allocated and flow within a [value] chain’’ (Gereffi and Korzeniewicz, 1994, p. 97). In international business literature, two traditional governance modes have
  • 55. explained how firms operate abroad: based on hierarchy or on the market. In other words, firms have to deal with the make-or-buy decision enounced in the transaction cost the- ory (Coase, 1937; Williamson, 1975). However, it seems that explaining the global configuration of value chain activities merely through a hierarchical or a market structure (the two extremes) is far from the reality. As Jacobides and Billinger (2006) explain, firms can also use alliances and generate par- tial integration with mixed modes. When global value chains are analyzed, a range of governance options thus emerge (see Fig. 2). At one end we find the market governance mode and at the other, the hierarchy mode. The former implies relatively Relational supplier HighLow Degree of explicit coordination Degree of power asymm etry Relati onal Capti ve HierarchyMarket Modular Materials End Use
  • 56. V al ue C ha in s Suppliers Custome rs Price Component and mat erial suppliers Component and mat erial suppliers Turn- key Lead firm Lead firm
  • 57. Integrat ed FirmLead firm Relational supplier Capti ve suppliers Figure 2 Global value chain governance modes (Gereffi et al., 2005, p. 89). simple transactions between the firms involved. Under this structure, buyers and suppliers along the value chain need little cooperation and the cost of switching to new part- ners is low for both. Price is the mechanism for reaching the deal (Gereffi and Fernandez-Stark, 2011). The tendency, however, is that firms within the global value chain are ever more connected, creating a network of independent firms orchestrated or coordinated by a leading firm, and providing a context of trust and power within volatile environments (Buckley, 2016). At the other end, we find the hierarchi- cal governance mode, which implies vertical integration and managerial control within the lead firm. Although it is less and less common to find firms integrating the whole value chain, there is research that has focused on examining global