SlideShare a Scribd company logo
1 of 22
Download to read offline
The Relationship between Wage and Inflation: Case of Slovenia and
Selected Central and Eastern European Countries
1
Helios Padilla Mayer, PhD
Government of Republic of Slovenia
Institute for Macroeconomic Analysis and Research
Gregorčičeva 27,1000 Ljubljana
January, 2003
1
hpadillamayer@gmail.com
2
Abstract:
In the paper we test the new Phillips curve for Central and Eastern European EU
accession countries for the period from 1990 to 2002 and use it to compare the efficiency
of the traditional Phillips curve. More specifically, we want to see whether real marginal
cost, which includes labor productivity and real wage components, can account for
inflation dynamics in the observed sample. Surprisingly, when observing all eight
selected countries, the relation between real marginal cost and inflation is opposite than
expected. On the other hand, inflation in Baltic States and Slovenia seems to be
influenced by real marginal cost. The elasticity coefficient of real wages on inflation for
Slovenia shows that inflation was quite responsive to movement in wages during the total
period, however, inflation became quite inelastic with respect to wages after 2000. Thus,
economic policies that were introduced in Slovenia after 2000 were quite efficient in
wage regulation, although the real effect will be observed in a more advanced period.
3
1. Introduction
One of the main tasks of the Central Banks of EU accession countries is to achieve price
stability and therefore it is really important to determine sources and nature of inflation in
this area. Our research targets effects of wages on inflation. Or, more precisely, we try
to see whether there is an evidence of wage pressures on inflation.
The most conventional model used for testing this relation is the standard Phillips curve
approach. However, we follow Gali, Gertler and Lopez-Salido (2001) and test relation
between wages and inflation on the basis of so called “new” Phillips curve literature. As
the standard Phillips curve, also this one assumes that inflation varies positively with real
sector economic activity in the short run. However, the difference is that the new Phillips
curve relates inflation to movements in real marginal cost. Thus, real marginal cost is the
theoretically appropriate measure of real sector inflationary pressures, as opposed to the
cyclical measures used in traditional Phillips curve analysis, such as detrended output and
unemployment.
One of the advantages of the real marginal cost measure (which in our analysis
corresponds to real unit labor cost) is that it directly accounts for the influence of both
productivity and wage pressures on inflation. Thus, according to the new Phillips curve
theory, productivity, wages and inflation follow the similar path. We want to see whether
this relation holds for Central and Eastern European EU accession countries (Czech
Republic, Hungary, Estonia, Latvia, Lithuania, Poland, Slovakia and Slovenia). More
specifically, we want to test whether wages did have inflationary pressures in Slovenia
and if so, what policy measures can be implemented to avoid this effect.
In section 2 we first present analyze the connection between inflation and wages on the
basis of traditional Phillips curve approach. Then, in section 3 we discuss the new
Phillips curve. Section 4 develops the theoretical model used for estimation. Section 5
presents empirical results and draws comparisons between the full country sample and
two sub-samples (Baltic States including Slovenia and Central European Countries).
Section 6 concludes.
4
2. Traditional Phillips Curve
The traditional Phillips curve relates inflation to some cyclical indicator (either level of
unemployment of real GDP) and lagged values of inflation. In our analysis, we are going
to use the real GDP as the cyclical indicator. Thus, if πt denotes inflation and the log
deviation of GDP from its long run trend, then the common specification of the Phillips
curve is:
, (1)
where is a random disturbance. This equation can be understood as a demand-side
explanation of inflation; aggregate demand increases following a rise in money supply.2
It is sometimes assumed that the sum of weights on lagged inflation equals to one so that
there is no long-run tradeoff between inflation and output. We did not impose this
assumption in our analysis because coefficients on lagged inflation variables in the
regression equation added up close to one.
We run the generalized least squares (GLS) regression controlling for fixed effects3
based
on equation (1) for the full country sample, and then (due to their differences) two sub-
samples, (a) Central and Eastern European countries, and (b) Baltic States and Slovenia.4
We use quarterly data from 1990 to 2002.5
We run several regressions and the one where
we use four lags for inflation fits best the quarterly data. To measure inflation we use log
difference of the CPI index, which we obtain from national statistic databases on a
quarterly basis. The output term is HP filtered real GDP on a quarterly basis. We also
obtain data on quarterly real GDP from national statistic databases. Figure 2.1 shows
inflation rate for Slovenia and Central and Eastern European EU candidate countries on a
2
For example, an increase in price level can be caused by a rise in aggregate demand, which is due to an
expansionary fiscal policy.
3
Due to heteroskedasticity of data and autocorrelation in the data series, ordinary least square (OLS)
estimates are not most efficient, so instead we choose to run the GLS regression and obtain unbiased as
well as most efficient coefficients.
4
We also run the regression for Slovenian data only, but since the size and sign of coefficients do not
change significantly, we only report regression results on the two sub-samples.
5
We do not include data for first two quarters of 2003 because it is not available for the full country
sample.
tyˆ
tt
h
i
tit y edpgp ++= -
=
-å 1
1
1 ˆ
te
5
yearly basis (average inflation rate).6
Figure 2.2 plots the real GDP growth rates for the
same country sample on a yearly basis.
The corresponding equation for the full data set is:
where standard errors are shown in parentheses. The estimates for the two sub-samples
are as follows:
(1)  Baltic States with Slovenia
(2)  Central European Countries
Surprisingly, in all three cases, there is a negative relation between the HP filtered output
and current inflation. Coefficients on output for the full sample and a sub-sample for
Baltic States and Slovenia are significant at 5 percent level, but the coefficient on Central
European countries is not significant. Gali, Gertler and Lopez-Salido (2001) on the other
hand show that there was a positive relation between the detrended output and inflation,
6
For the purpose of presentation, inflation rates are expressed in logarithmic form.
u_i)toduevarianceof(fraction0.431rho
0.00value-p61.17,statisticF
(0.073)
yˆ0.129-0.112045.0239.0567.0
(0.951)(0.095)(0.132)(0.137)
1-t4321
=
==
+-+= ---- ttttt ppppp
u_i)toduevarianceof(fraction0.498rho
0.00value-p52.28,statisticF
(0.148)
yˆ0.376-0.157105.0302.0347.0
(0.172)(0.143)(0.193)(0.219)
1-t4321
=
==
-++= ---- ttttt ppppp
u_i)toduevarianceof(fraction0.109rho
0.00value-p12.84,statisticF
(0.667)
yˆ0.026-0.161046.0044.0618.0
(0.093)(0.115)(0.160)(0.145)
1-t4321
=
==
+-+= ---- ttttt ppppp
6
which actually corresponds to the real essence of the traditional Phillips curve. Thus, the
traditional Phillips curve is not really able to explain the stability of relation between
inflation and output over the observed period nor account for the policy reforms that were
introduced in these countries in order to suppress inflation. Moreover, coefficients on
lagged inflation may very well embed expectations of future inflation. Hence, it is
necessary to remodel the traditional Phillips curve in order to observe the whether
inflation can be better explained through the supply side of the economy.
3. The New Phillips Curve
The new Phillips curve is based on staggered nominal price setting (Taylor, 1980). The
price setting behavior is based on optimization by monopolistically competitive firms.
The basic equation that we are going to test is the one that relates inflation πt to the
anticipated future inflation πt+1 and real marginal cost:
(2)
where is the average real marginal cost, in percent deviation from its steady state
level, β is subjective discount factor, and λ is the slope coefficient that depends on the
parameters of the model. This equation shows direct effects of the frictions in the price
adjustment process that are the key aspects of the theory (Gali,Gertler,Lopez-Salido,
2001).
Nevertheless, the new Phillips curve literature (Goodfriend and King, 1997) relates
inflation to an output gap variable.7
Assuming restrictions on technology and labor
market structure, real marginal cost are proportionally related to the output gap
(Rotemberg and Woodford, 1997),
, (3)
( ) tttt ME ˆ
1 lpbp += +
tMˆ
)(ˆ *
ttt yyM -= d
7
where are the logarithms of real output and the natural level of real output,
respectively. Combining equations (2) and (3) results in the standard output gap based
for relations of the new Phillips curve.
, (4)
where .
However, in the literature equation (4) has been the subject of a considerable discussion.
According to the traditional Phillips curve, inflation varies positively with the output gap.
On the other hand, in the new Phillips curve context, inflation is an entirely forward-
looking phenomenon. By iterating equation (4) forward we get:
, (5)
This equation shows that if a central bank can commit to stabilizing the output gap
, it can reach price stability. On the other side this equation also suggest
that inflation should anticipate movements in the output gap. So far, as the
approximation of the traditional Phillips curve recommend, the output gap tends to lead
inflation. Gali, Gertler, and Lopez-Salido, 2001, Sbordone, 1999, and Gali and Gertler,
1999 have shown that this relation holds for the US as well as for the EU countries.
Thus, the output gap formulation of the new Phillips curve cannot account for the
persistence of inflation either for the US or the EU countries.
Nevertheless, above mention authors find that the relation between inflation and real
marginal cost given by equation (2) is some how consistent with the data. Thus, the link
between the real marginal cost and the output gap corresponds with data. It seems that
7
For a detailed discussion on output gap refer to Bovha Padilla and Padilla Mayer, 2002.
*
and tt yy
( ) )( *
1 ttttt yykE -+= +pbp
ld=k
)( *
0
ktktt
k
k
t yyEk ++
¥
=
-= åbp
)( *
ktkt yy ++ -
8
real marginal cost response sluggishly to output gap movements, the same way as
inflation does. The first possible explanation for that is that conventional measures of the
output gap are not adequate. It may not be appropriate to use detrended output to
estimate the output gap if there are significant real shocks to the economy. The second
explanation could be that there are rigidities in the labor market (either in the form of real
or nominal wage rigidities), which break down the relation between marginal cost and
output gap (equation 3). These rigidities offer an explanation for inactive behavior of
real marginal cost.
4. The Baseline Model
In this section we present relation between inflation and real marginal cost across firms.
As Gali, Gertler and Lopez-Salido, 2001, we assume that firms face increasing real
marginal cost.8
We assume that there is a continuum of firms indexed by . Each firm is a
monopolistic competitor, it produces a differentiated good , and sells it at nominal
price . The demand curve that each firm faces is then , where
and are aggregate output and aggregate price, respectively. The production
function for firm is given by , where is a technological
parameter, is employment, and a is the share of labor in income.
Firms set nominal prices on a reel basis as in Calvo, 1983. Each firm resets its price with
probability each period, while a fraction of producers leave their prices
unchanged. Thus, the expected time that the price remains fixed is and the
parameter then shows the degree of price rigidity.
[ ]1,0Îj
( )jYt
( )jPt ( )
( )
t
t
t
t Y
P
jP
jY
e-
÷÷
ø
ö
çç
è
æ
=
tY tP
j ( ) ( ) a-
= 1
jLAjY ttt tA
( )jLt
q-1 q
q-1
1
q
9
The price level can be expressed as a function of the newly set price and the lagged
price .9
(6)
All firms that change price in period choose the same value of . A firm that is able
to reset price in period chooses price to maximize expected discounted profits given
technology, factor prices and the constraint on price adjustment (defined by the reset
probability ). An optimizing firm will set according to the following log-linear
rule:
, (7)
where is a discount factor, is the logarithm of nominal marginal cost in
period of a firm that last reset its price in period , and is the firm´s
desired gross markup.
We need to find an expression for inflation in terms of an observable measure of
aggregate marginal cost. By cost minimizing rule the firm´s real marginal cost equals the
real wage divided by the marginal product of labor. Given the Cobb-Douglass
production function, the real marginal cost is given by ,
where and are output and employment for a firm that has set price in at the
8
Allowing marginal cost to vary across firms gives more reliable estimates of the degree of price rigidity in
the Euro area as showing in Gali, Gertler and Lopez-Salido, 2001.
9
This expression is obtained after log-linearizing the price index around zero inflation steady state and it is
taken in a log form.
tp *
tp
1-tp
1
*
)1( -+-= ttt ppp qq
t
*
tp
t
q-1 *
tp
( ) ( ) ( )n
kttt
k
k
t MEp +
¥
=
å-+= ,
0
*
1log bqbqµ
b ( )n
kttM +,
kt + t
1-
=
e
e
µ
( )
( )( )kttktt
ktkt
ktt
LY
PW
M
++
++
+
-
=
,,
,
/1
/
a
kttY +, kttL +, t
10
optimal value . Since we cannot observe individual firm marginal cost (absence of
firm level data), we define “average” marginal cost, which depends only on aggregates:
(8)
By exploiting the assumptions of Cobb-Douglas production function and isoelastic
demand curve, we obtain the following log-linear relation between and :
(9)
where and are the log deviations of and from their respective
steady state values.
We obtain the formulation of the new Phillips curve that relates inflation to the real
marginal cost by combining equations (6), (7), and (9),
, where (10)
(11)
Slope of the coefficient depends of parameters of the model. is decreasing in the
degree of price rigidity, , which shows the fraction of firms that keep their prices
constant. Thus, the smaller the fraction of firms that adjust prices, the less sensitive
inflation will be to movements in marginal cost. Moreover, is also decreasing in the
slope of production function, measured by , and in the elasticity of demand, . The
larger and , the more sensitive is the marginal cost of an individual firm to
deviations of its price from the average price level. Finally, the model suggests that
inflation should equal a discounted stream of expected future average real marginal costs.
*
tP
( )
( )( )tt
tt
t
LY
PW
M
/1
/
a-
=
kttM +, tM
)(
1
ˆˆ *
, kttktktt ppMM +++ -
-
-=
a
ea
kttM +,
ˆ
ktM +
ˆ
kttM +, tM
( ) tttt ME ˆ
1 lpbp += +
[ ])1(1
)1)(1)(1(
-+
---
=
eaq
abqq
l
l l
q
l
a e
a e
11
5. Empirical Results
In this section we present estimates of the baseline model (equation 10) for the sample of
selected EU candidate countries. Since we are interested to observe whether Slovenia
follows the full sample, we also perform analysis of Slovenia inflation dynamics
separately.
We use quarterly data from 1990 to 2002.10
Data for inflation and real GDP are obtained
from the Countries in Transition CD-Rom (on a yearly basis), WIIW, and quarterly series
are obtained from the national statistical offices. Inflation is given as a percentage
change in prices with respect to the previous year, and the real GDP data are given in
1995 prices.
We calculate average real marginal cost (equation 8) in the following way. First, we
obtain data on gross monthly real wages per capita, quarterly data on real GDP and labor
force. Since we calculate quarterly marginal cost, we set up the nominator as a sum of
the three month gross real wages per capita. We also need data on labor income share,
which we calculate according to Dobrinsky (2001). He presented a measure of capital
income share for countries in transition. According to him, the capital income share can
be calculated as the share of gross operating surplus and gross mixed income compared to
total factor incomes.11
Thus, the labor income share is simply calculated as a share of
compensation of employees compared to total factor incomes. Since we cannot obtain
quarterly data on compensation of employees and total factor income, we use yearly data
and therefore calculate labor income share on a yearly basis. However, we believe that
this share is not varying significantly during the year and we use it for calculating
quarterly real average marginal cost. Thus, the denominator is calculated as a product of
annual labor income share and ratio of a real GDP and labor force on a quarterly basis.
Then, we use the log deviation of real marginal cost from its mean as a measure of .
10
We do not include data for first two quarters of 2003 because it is not available for the full country
sample.
11
Total factor incomes can be calculated as the difference between the nominal GDP and net indirect taxes.
tMˆ
12
Figures 5.1 and 5.2 show our measure of real marginal costs along with inflation for
Central and Eastern European EU Candidate Countries. Surprisingly, when we take into
account the full sample, variables do not move closely together. Although correlation
between inflation and real marginal costs is positive, it is extremely small and non-
significant. Thus, it is hard to say that inflation is really related to movements in
marginal costs as suggested by the theory explained in Section 4.
Moreover, Table 5.1 shows correlation between inflation and real marginal cost for all
countries that are in the sample. Inflation could be best explained by variation in real
marginal cost in Baltic region (Estonia, Latvia and Lithuania). Correlation between both
variables is relatively high also for Slovenia. Moreover, elasticity coefficient for
Slovenia shows that inflation is relatively responsive on real wages. Increasing wages by
1 percent would increase inflation by 2.76 percent. Thus, according to the real data from
the observed period, wages did have inflationary pressures in Slovenia. On the other
hand, there is strong negative correlation between inflation and real marginal cost in
Poland, Czech Republic, Slovakia and Hungary.
Table 5.1: Correlation between Real Marginal Cost and Inflation
We then present empirical estimates of coefficients in equation (9). First, we present
estimates of the baseline model for the full sample, and then for two sub-samples: (1)
Country Correlation
Czech Republic -0.73
Estonia 0.73
Hungary -0.06
Latvia 0.66
Lithuania 0.63
Poland -0.83
Slovakia -0.55
Slovenia 0.52
Average 0.04
13
Baltic States with Slovenia, and (2) Central European countries. We show that in
contrast with findings for the Euro area and the USA (Gali, Gertler, Lopez-Salido, 2001)
this model does not explain the dynamics of inflation in the Central and Eastern European
EU candidate countries in expected way.
5.1. Baseline Model Estimates
We estimate the coefficients in equation (9) by using generalized method of moments
(GMM). Under rational expectations, equation (9) defines the set of orthogonality
conditions:
,
where zt denotes a vector of variables observed in time t, that is, instrumental variables.
The optimal choice of instrumental variables are lags of explanatory variables already
presented in the model: lags of inflation, lags of real marginal cost and detrended output.
Since the data series consists only from 52 observations (per country), we choose
relatively small number of lags for instruments in order to minimize the potential
estimation bias that can arise in small samples. As Gali, Gertler and Lopez-Salido, 2001,
we use four lags of inflation, two lags of the real marginal costs, and detrended output.12
The corresponding equation for the full data set is:
where standard errors are shown in parentheses. The estimates for the two sub-samples13
are as follows:
12
We tried to estimate coefficients with using more than four lags for inflation and more than two lags for
the real marginal costs, but results were not affected.
( )( ) 01 =-- + ttttt zmcE lbpp
0.01value-p5.24,statisticJ
0.00value-p16.20,statisticFˆ271.4)(2215.0
(1.132)(0.073)
1
==
==-= + tttt ME pp
14
(1)  Baltic States with Slovenia
(2)  Central European Countries
In all three equations, standard errors are modified using a Newey-West correction to
account for serial correlation in the error terms. Also, we take care of fixed effects in all
three regressions.
In order to check for potential weakness of the instruments, we perform an F-test applied
to the first stage regression. Results show that instruments that we use are relevant (see F
statistic in above regressions). We also test for overidentifying restrictions of the
model.14
On the basis of Hansen test, we reject overidentifying restrictions for all three
regressions (see J statistic in above regression).
In general, the empirical model does not work as expected in the full sample and in the
sub-sample of Central European countries (Czech Republic, Slovakia, Poland). The
coefficients on marginal cost are negative and significant at 5 percent level in both cases.
The only case that coefficient is positive and significant as implied by the theory is in the
case of Baltic States including Slovenia. This result is in contrast with findings of Gali,
Gertler, and Lopez-Salido, 2001, where they estimate positive and highly significant
effect of marginal cost on inflation in the Euro area and the USA.15
13
Again, we run an individual regression analysis for Slovenia, but since the size and significance of
coefficients do not change, we report results only on the two sub-samples.
14
The model is overidentified is there is more than one way to calculate its parameters from the reduced
form parameters, leading to restrictions on the reduced form parameters.
15
However, we need to take into the account that the findings for the Euro are and the USA are based on
the quarterly data set from 1970 to 1998. After that time there has been a decline in unemployment and a
J(1.738)(0.103) 0.01value-p4.22,statistic
0.00value-p13.73,statisticFˆ649.3)(314.0 1
==
==+= + tttt ME pp
J(0.772)(0.082) 0.01value-p4.65,statistic
0.00value-p18.65,statisticFˆ695.3)(178.0 1
==
==-= + tttt ME pp
15
6. Final Remarks
Our results indicate that neither traditional nor a marginal cost-based Phillips curves do
not provide a satisfactory explanation of Central and Eastern European area inflation
from 1990 to 2002. First, due to policy reforms that were oriented toward reduction of
inflation in the post transition period, the traditional Phillips curve did not show the
positive relation between the output and price level neither in the full sample nor in the
two sub-samples. The new Phillips curve model suggests that marginal cost is negatively
related to inflation for the full sample. On the other hand, results for Baltic States and
Slovenia are in accordance with the model prediction.
According to this information, wages in Slovenia did have inflationary pressures.
However, one should be aware that this result is obtained on the basis of quarterly data
from 1990 to 2002. Since 2000 there have been wage policies introduced which allowed
the increase of wages only with respect to an increase in productivity and thus should not
have inflationary pressures. Indeed, if one checks the elasticity of wages with respect to
inflation on the basis of data from 2000 on, the coefficient drops to 0.67 percent (with
respect to 2.76 percent when full period data is taken into account). However, if one runs
the regression on the basis of the new Phillips curve with the data from 2000 on, results
do not change: there is still positive and significant relation between real marginal cost
and inflation.
Therefore, at this point it is hard to say how marginal cost really affects inflation
dynamics and thus give more precise policy recommendations. It would be appropriate
to decompose the movement in real marginal cost in order to isolate the factors that drive
this variable. One possible decomposition is into a component that accounts for labor
market frictions (measured as the wage markup) and the other one that would correspond
to the frictionless competitive equilibrium.
rise in the output growth in the Euro area, without any corresponding rise in inflation. Thus, including more
recent period in the analysis of Euro inflation dynamics may alter results.
16
Moreover, to determine whether wages really have inflationary pressures on selected
countries in the observed sample, it is necessary to understand the determinants of the
wage markup. Nevertheless, it will be necessary to include in the analysis additional
factors, such as union pressures, that would account for variation in the wage markup and
thus explain its effect on inflation dynamics of Central and Eastern European EU
candidate countries.
7. References
1.   Bovha Padilla, S. and H. Padilla Mayer, 2002. “Sources of GDP Growth, Potential
Output and Output Gap for Slovenia: Mid-Term Analysis”, IB Review, Institute for
Macroeconomic Analysis and Development, Ljubljana, Slovenia, June 2002.
2.   Bovha Padilla, S. and H. Padilla Mayer, 2002. “Sources of Growth in Selected
Central and Eastern European Countries”, Countries in Transition International
Conference, Kranjska Gora, Slovenia, June 2003.
3.   Calvo, G., 1983. “Staggered Prices in a Utility Maximizing Framework”, Journal of
Monetary Economics, 12, 383-398.
4.   Eurostat, 1997-2003. “Statistical Information”, various issues.
5.   Eurostat, 1997-2002. “Statistical Yearbook for Central and Eastern European
Countries”, various issues.
6.   Gali, J. and M. Gertler, 1999. “Inflation Dynamics: A Structural Econometric
Analysis”, Journal of Monetary Economics, 44, 195-222.
7.   Gali, J., M. Gertler and J. Lopez-Salido, 2001. “European Inflation Dynamics”,
NBER Working Paper Series, Working Paper 8218, 39 pp.
8.   Goodfriend, M. and R. King, 1997. “The New Neoclassical Synthesis”, in NBER
Macroeconomic Annual, Ben Bernanke and Julio Rotemberg, eds., MIT Press.
9.   Intriligator, M., R. Bodkin, and C, Hsiao, 1978. “Econometric Models, Techniques
and Applications”, Prentice Hall, Upper Saddle River, NJ.
10.  Rotemberg, J. and M. Woodford, 1997. “An Optimization-based Economic
Framework for the Evaluation of Monetary Policy”, in NBER Macroeconomic
Annual, Ben Bernanke and Julio Rotemberg, eds., MIT Press.
11.  Sbordone, A., 1999. “Prices and Unit Labor Costs: A New Test of Price Stickiness”,
mimeo, Rutgers University.
12.  Taylor, J., 1980. “Aggregate Dynamics and Staggered Contracts”, Journal of
Monetary Economics, 44, 293-335.
13.  WIIW: Countries in Transition 2002, CD-Rom.
17
Figure 2.1: Inflation in Slovenia and Central and Eastern European EU Candidate Countries
from 1990 to 2002 (log form)
Source: Countries in Transition 2002, WIIW, Eurostat, selected publications.
Figure 2.2: Real GDP Growth Rates in Slovenia and Central and Eastern European EU
Candidate Countries from 1990 to 2002, in percent
Source: Countries in Transition 2002, WIIW, Eurostat, selected publications.
-­5.5
3.22.9
4.6
5.2
3.8
4.6
3.5
4.1
5.3
2.8
-­8.9
-­4.7
-­12
-­10
-­8
-­6
-­4
-­2
0
2
4
6
1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002
in  %
Slovenia
Average
1.97
2.132.19
1.81
2.07
2.12
2.29
2.60
3.04
3.49
5.33
4.74
6.31
1.5
2
2.5
3
3.5
4
4.5
5
5.5
6
6.5
1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002
ln  Inflation
Average
Slovenia
18
Figure 5.1: Inflation and Real Marginal Cost in Central and Eastern European EU Candidate
Countries*
* Data are in logarithmic forms. Left-side scale measures inflation and the right-side scale measures
real marginal costs as explained in Sections 3 and 4.
Source: Authors´calculations.
Figure 5.2: Inflation and Real Marginal Cost in Central and Eastern European EU Candidate
Countries*
a)   Czech Republic
0
1
2
3
4
5
6
1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002
-­0.04
-­0.02
0
0.02
0.04
0.06
0.08
Inflation
Real  Marginal  Cost
0
0.5
1
1.5
2
2.5
3
3.5
4
4.5
1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002
-­0.5
-­0.4
-­0.3
-­0.2
-­0.1
0
0.1
0.2
Inflation
Real  Marginal  Cost
19
b)   Estonia
c)   Hungary
0
0.5
1
1.5
2
2.5
3
3.5
4
4.5
5
1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002
-­0.1
-­0.05
0
0.05
0.1
0.15
0.2
Inflation
Real  Marginal  Cost
0
0.5
1
1.5
2
2.5
3
3.5
4
1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002
-­0.1
-­0.05
0
0.05
0.1
0.15
Inflation
Real  Marginal  Cost
20
d)   Latvia
e)   Lithuania
0
1
2
3
4
5
6
1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002
-­0.25
-­0.2
-­0.15
-­0.1
-­0.05
0
0.05
0.1
0.15
Inflation
Real  Marginal  Cost
-­2
-­1
0
1
2
3
4
5
6
7
1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002
-­0.2
-­0.1
0
0.1
0.2
0.3
0.4
Inflation
Real  Marginal  Cost
21
f)   Poland
g)   Slovak Republic
0
1
2
3
4
5
6
7
1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002
-­0.4
-­0.3
-­0.2
-­0.1
0
0.1
0.2
0.3
Inflation
Real  Marginal  Cost
0
0.5
1
1.5
2
2.5
3
3.5
4
4.5
1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002
-­0.2
-­0.15
-­0.1
-­0.05
0
0.05
0.1
0.15
0.2
0.25
0.3
Inflation
Real  Marginal  Cost
22
h)   Slovenia
* Data are in logarithmic forms. Left-side scale measures inflation and the right side scale measures
real marginal costs as explained in Sections 3 and 4.
Source: Authors´calculations.
0
1
2
3
4
5
6
7
1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002
-­0.08
-­0.06
-­0.04
-­0.02
0
0.02
0.04
0.06
Inflation
Real  Marginal  Cost

More Related Content

What's hot

Job Mobility and Creative Destruction: Flexicurity in the Land of Schumpteter...
Job Mobility and Creative Destruction: Flexicurity in the Land of Schumpteter...Job Mobility and Creative Destruction: Flexicurity in the Land of Schumpteter...
Job Mobility and Creative Destruction: Flexicurity in the Land of Schumpteter...ADEMU_Project
 
The Relationship Between Keynesian Militarism and Economic Growth
The Relationship Between Keynesian Militarism and Economic GrowthThe Relationship Between Keynesian Militarism and Economic Growth
The Relationship Between Keynesian Militarism and Economic Growthpkconference
 
The relationship between nominal interest rates and inflation new evidence a...
The relationship between nominal interest rates and inflation  new evidence a...The relationship between nominal interest rates and inflation  new evidence a...
The relationship between nominal interest rates and inflation new evidence a...Alexander Decker
 
Workhour haircut an instrument in times of economic crisis
Workhour haircut   an instrument in times of economic crisisWorkhour haircut   an instrument in times of economic crisis
Workhour haircut an instrument in times of economic crisisRam Madhavan
 
Structural breaks, unit root tests and long time series
Structural breaks, unit root tests and long time seriesStructural breaks, unit root tests and long time series
Structural breaks, unit root tests and long time seriesArup Guha
 
Parac hacer Macroeconomia Necesitamos Fundamentos Microeconomicos
Parac hacer Macroeconomia Necesitamos Fundamentos MicroeconomicosParac hacer Macroeconomia Necesitamos Fundamentos Microeconomicos
Parac hacer Macroeconomia Necesitamos Fundamentos MicroeconomicosPAD Ancash
 
yieldCurve
yieldCurveyieldCurve
yieldCurveJI WANG
 
How has Income Inequality and Wage Disparity Between Native and Foreign Sub-p...
How has Income Inequality and Wage Disparity Between Native and Foreign Sub-p...How has Income Inequality and Wage Disparity Between Native and Foreign Sub-p...
How has Income Inequality and Wage Disparity Between Native and Foreign Sub-p...Dinal Shah
 
The (Nonlinear) relationship between Exchange rate uncertainty and trade. An ...
The (Nonlinear) relationship between Exchange rate uncertainty and trade. An ...The (Nonlinear) relationship between Exchange rate uncertainty and trade. An ...
The (Nonlinear) relationship between Exchange rate uncertainty and trade. An ...IOSR Journals
 
Traditional convergence tests with Penn World Table 9.01
Traditional convergence tests with Penn World Table 9.01Traditional convergence tests with Penn World Table 9.01
Traditional convergence tests with Penn World Table 9.01Palkansaajien tutkimuslaitos
 
Eco Basic 1 8
Eco Basic 1 8Eco Basic 1 8
Eco Basic 1 8kit11229
 
An empirical analysis of the incidence of corporate income tax
An empirical analysis of the incidence of corporate income taxAn empirical analysis of the incidence of corporate income tax
An empirical analysis of the incidence of corporate income taxAlexander Decker
 

What's hot (20)

Current wage pressures in some EU countries
Current wage pressures in some EU countriesCurrent wage pressures in some EU countries
Current wage pressures in some EU countries
 
Job Mobility and Creative Destruction: Flexicurity in the Land of Schumpteter...
Job Mobility and Creative Destruction: Flexicurity in the Land of Schumpteter...Job Mobility and Creative Destruction: Flexicurity in the Land of Schumpteter...
Job Mobility and Creative Destruction: Flexicurity in the Land of Schumpteter...
 
Inflation: Origin and Global Dynamics
Inflation: Origin and Global DynamicsInflation: Origin and Global Dynamics
Inflation: Origin and Global Dynamics
 
The Relationship Between Keynesian Militarism and Economic Growth
The Relationship Between Keynesian Militarism and Economic GrowthThe Relationship Between Keynesian Militarism and Economic Growth
The Relationship Between Keynesian Militarism and Economic Growth
 
Vol7no2 6
Vol7no2 6Vol7no2 6
Vol7no2 6
 
The relationship between nominal interest rates and inflation new evidence a...
The relationship between nominal interest rates and inflation  new evidence a...The relationship between nominal interest rates and inflation  new evidence a...
The relationship between nominal interest rates and inflation new evidence a...
 
Workhour haircut an instrument in times of economic crisis
Workhour haircut   an instrument in times of economic crisisWorkhour haircut   an instrument in times of economic crisis
Workhour haircut an instrument in times of economic crisis
 
Structural breaks, unit root tests and long time series
Structural breaks, unit root tests and long time seriesStructural breaks, unit root tests and long time series
Structural breaks, unit root tests and long time series
 
Parac hacer Macroeconomia Necesitamos Fundamentos Microeconomicos
Parac hacer Macroeconomia Necesitamos Fundamentos MicroeconomicosParac hacer Macroeconomia Necesitamos Fundamentos Microeconomicos
Parac hacer Macroeconomia Necesitamos Fundamentos Microeconomicos
 
A spatio temporal model of house prices in the us
A spatio temporal model of house prices in the usA spatio temporal model of house prices in the us
A spatio temporal model of house prices in the us
 
yieldCurve
yieldCurveyieldCurve
yieldCurve
 
How has Income Inequality and Wage Disparity Between Native and Foreign Sub-p...
How has Income Inequality and Wage Disparity Between Native and Foreign Sub-p...How has Income Inequality and Wage Disparity Between Native and Foreign Sub-p...
How has Income Inequality and Wage Disparity Between Native and Foreign Sub-p...
 
The (Nonlinear) relationship between Exchange rate uncertainty and trade. An ...
The (Nonlinear) relationship between Exchange rate uncertainty and trade. An ...The (Nonlinear) relationship between Exchange rate uncertainty and trade. An ...
The (Nonlinear) relationship between Exchange rate uncertainty and trade. An ...
 
Meco and stock
Meco and stockMeco and stock
Meco and stock
 
Froyen10
Froyen10Froyen10
Froyen10
 
Optimal Discretionary Monetary Policy in A Potential Zero Lower Bound Framework
Optimal Discretionary Monetary Policy in A Potential Zero Lower Bound FrameworkOptimal Discretionary Monetary Policy in A Potential Zero Lower Bound Framework
Optimal Discretionary Monetary Policy in A Potential Zero Lower Bound Framework
 
Traditional convergence tests with Penn World Table 9.01
Traditional convergence tests with Penn World Table 9.01Traditional convergence tests with Penn World Table 9.01
Traditional convergence tests with Penn World Table 9.01
 
Eco Basic 1 8
Eco Basic 1 8Eco Basic 1 8
Eco Basic 1 8
 
An empirical analysis of the incidence of corporate income tax
An empirical analysis of the incidence of corporate income taxAn empirical analysis of the incidence of corporate income tax
An empirical analysis of the incidence of corporate income tax
 
First Version
First VersionFirst Version
First Version
 

Similar to The Relationship between Wage and Inflation

The Causal Analysis of the Relationship between Inflation and Output Gap in T...
The Causal Analysis of the Relationship between Inflation and Output Gap in T...The Causal Analysis of the Relationship between Inflation and Output Gap in T...
The Causal Analysis of the Relationship between Inflation and Output Gap in T...inventionjournals
 
Macroeconomic relationships
Macroeconomic relationshipsMacroeconomic relationships
Macroeconomic relationshipsGaetan Lion
 
What Causes Economic Growth? A Breakdown of The Solow Growth Model
What Causes Economic Growth? A Breakdown of The Solow Growth ModelWhat Causes Economic Growth? A Breakdown of The Solow Growth Model
What Causes Economic Growth? A Breakdown of The Solow Growth ModelJaredBilberry1
 
Javier Ordóñez. Real unit labour costs in Eurozone countries: Drivers and clu...
Javier Ordóñez. Real unit labour costs in Eurozone countries: Drivers and clu...Javier Ordóñez. Real unit labour costs in Eurozone countries: Drivers and clu...
Javier Ordóñez. Real unit labour costs in Eurozone countries: Drivers and clu...Eesti Pank
 
A. Krasovskii, D. Pisarenko, Modeling Control of Population Dynamics in Russi...
A. Krasovskii, D. Pisarenko, Modeling Control of Population Dynamics in Russi...A. Krasovskii, D. Pisarenko, Modeling Control of Population Dynamics in Russi...
A. Krasovskii, D. Pisarenko, Modeling Control of Population Dynamics in Russi...Dmitri Pisarenko
 
The impact of inflation, policy rate and government consumption expenditure o...
The impact of inflation, policy rate and government consumption expenditure o...The impact of inflation, policy rate and government consumption expenditure o...
The impact of inflation, policy rate and government consumption expenditure o...Alexander Decker
 
A Primer on Cointegration: Application to Nigerian Gross Domestic Product and...
A Primer on Cointegration: Application to Nigerian Gross Domestic Product and...A Primer on Cointegration: Application to Nigerian Gross Domestic Product and...
A Primer on Cointegration: Application to Nigerian Gross Domestic Product and...IOSR Journals
 
Genuine%20 %2008%20-%20 inflation%20and%20unemployment
Genuine%20 %2008%20-%20 inflation%20and%20unemploymentGenuine%20 %2008%20-%20 inflation%20and%20unemployment
Genuine%20 %2008%20-%20 inflation%20and%20unemploymentDaniseck Adam
 
Forecasting for Economics and Business 1st Edition Gloria Gonzalez Rivera Sol...
Forecasting for Economics and Business 1st Edition Gloria Gonzalez Rivera Sol...Forecasting for Economics and Business 1st Edition Gloria Gonzalez Rivera Sol...
Forecasting for Economics and Business 1st Edition Gloria Gonzalez Rivera Sol...vacenini
 
Degree exam 2019 q & a (1) (1)
Degree exam 2019 q & a (1) (1)Degree exam 2019 q & a (1) (1)
Degree exam 2019 q & a (1) (1)OsamaKhan404075
 
Exchange rate regimes and macroeconomic perfomance zithe p. machewere
Exchange rate regimes and macroeconomic perfomance  zithe p. machewereExchange rate regimes and macroeconomic perfomance  zithe p. machewere
Exchange rate regimes and macroeconomic perfomance zithe p. machewereZithe Machewere
 
Empirical Finance, Jordan Stone- Linkedin
Empirical Finance, Jordan Stone- LinkedinEmpirical Finance, Jordan Stone- Linkedin
Empirical Finance, Jordan Stone- LinkedinJordan Stone
 
Labour Taxation and Employment: An Analysis with a Macroeconomic Model for th...
Labour Taxation and Employment: An Analysis with a Macroeconomic Model for th...Labour Taxation and Employment: An Analysis with a Macroeconomic Model for th...
Labour Taxation and Employment: An Analysis with a Macroeconomic Model for th...Palkansaajien tutkimuslaitos
 
Solutions Manual for Forecasting For Economics And Business 1st Edition by Gl...
Solutions Manual for Forecasting For Economics And Business 1st Edition by Gl...Solutions Manual for Forecasting For Economics And Business 1st Edition by Gl...
Solutions Manual for Forecasting For Economics And Business 1st Edition by Gl...HildaLa
 

Similar to The Relationship between Wage and Inflation (20)

Paper
PaperPaper
Paper
 
The Causal Analysis of the Relationship between Inflation and Output Gap in T...
The Causal Analysis of the Relationship between Inflation and Output Gap in T...The Causal Analysis of the Relationship between Inflation and Output Gap in T...
The Causal Analysis of the Relationship between Inflation and Output Gap in T...
 
Macroeconomic relationships
Macroeconomic relationshipsMacroeconomic relationships
Macroeconomic relationships
 
What Causes Economic Growth? A Breakdown of The Solow Growth Model
What Causes Economic Growth? A Breakdown of The Solow Growth ModelWhat Causes Economic Growth? A Breakdown of The Solow Growth Model
What Causes Economic Growth? A Breakdown of The Solow Growth Model
 
Javier Ordóñez. Real unit labour costs in Eurozone countries: Drivers and clu...
Javier Ordóñez. Real unit labour costs in Eurozone countries: Drivers and clu...Javier Ordóñez. Real unit labour costs in Eurozone countries: Drivers and clu...
Javier Ordóñez. Real unit labour costs in Eurozone countries: Drivers and clu...
 
A. Krasovskii, D. Pisarenko, Modeling Control of Population Dynamics in Russi...
A. Krasovskii, D. Pisarenko, Modeling Control of Population Dynamics in Russi...A. Krasovskii, D. Pisarenko, Modeling Control of Population Dynamics in Russi...
A. Krasovskii, D. Pisarenko, Modeling Control of Population Dynamics in Russi...
 
Unit3 hl
Unit3 hlUnit3 hl
Unit3 hl
 
The impact of inflation, policy rate and government consumption expenditure o...
The impact of inflation, policy rate and government consumption expenditure o...The impact of inflation, policy rate and government consumption expenditure o...
The impact of inflation, policy rate and government consumption expenditure o...
 
A Primer on Cointegration: Application to Nigerian Gross Domestic Product and...
A Primer on Cointegration: Application to Nigerian Gross Domestic Product and...A Primer on Cointegration: Application to Nigerian Gross Domestic Product and...
A Primer on Cointegration: Application to Nigerian Gross Domestic Product and...
 
Research presentation.By Hadiqa
Research presentation.By HadiqaResearch presentation.By Hadiqa
Research presentation.By Hadiqa
 
CASE Network Studies and Analyses 257 - Uneven Growth in a Monetary Union: on...
CASE Network Studies and Analyses 257 - Uneven Growth in a Monetary Union: on...CASE Network Studies and Analyses 257 - Uneven Growth in a Monetary Union: on...
CASE Network Studies and Analyses 257 - Uneven Growth in a Monetary Union: on...
 
Measures of the Output Gap in Turkey: An Empirical Assessment of Selected Met...
Measures of the Output Gap in Turkey: An Empirical Assessment of Selected Met...Measures of the Output Gap in Turkey: An Empirical Assessment of Selected Met...
Measures of the Output Gap in Turkey: An Empirical Assessment of Selected Met...
 
Can the Disparity between GDP and GDP Forecast Cause Economic Instability? Th...
Can the Disparity between GDP and GDP Forecast Cause Economic Instability? Th...Can the Disparity between GDP and GDP Forecast Cause Economic Instability? Th...
Can the Disparity between GDP and GDP Forecast Cause Economic Instability? Th...
 
Genuine%20 %2008%20-%20 inflation%20and%20unemployment
Genuine%20 %2008%20-%20 inflation%20and%20unemploymentGenuine%20 %2008%20-%20 inflation%20and%20unemployment
Genuine%20 %2008%20-%20 inflation%20and%20unemployment
 
Forecasting for Economics and Business 1st Edition Gloria Gonzalez Rivera Sol...
Forecasting for Economics and Business 1st Edition Gloria Gonzalez Rivera Sol...Forecasting for Economics and Business 1st Edition Gloria Gonzalez Rivera Sol...
Forecasting for Economics and Business 1st Edition Gloria Gonzalez Rivera Sol...
 
Degree exam 2019 q & a (1) (1)
Degree exam 2019 q & a (1) (1)Degree exam 2019 q & a (1) (1)
Degree exam 2019 q & a (1) (1)
 
Exchange rate regimes and macroeconomic perfomance zithe p. machewere
Exchange rate regimes and macroeconomic perfomance  zithe p. machewereExchange rate regimes and macroeconomic perfomance  zithe p. machewere
Exchange rate regimes and macroeconomic perfomance zithe p. machewere
 
Empirical Finance, Jordan Stone- Linkedin
Empirical Finance, Jordan Stone- LinkedinEmpirical Finance, Jordan Stone- Linkedin
Empirical Finance, Jordan Stone- Linkedin
 
Labour Taxation and Employment: An Analysis with a Macroeconomic Model for th...
Labour Taxation and Employment: An Analysis with a Macroeconomic Model for th...Labour Taxation and Employment: An Analysis with a Macroeconomic Model for th...
Labour Taxation and Employment: An Analysis with a Macroeconomic Model for th...
 
Solutions Manual for Forecasting For Economics And Business 1st Edition by Gl...
Solutions Manual for Forecasting For Economics And Business 1st Edition by Gl...Solutions Manual for Forecasting For Economics And Business 1st Edition by Gl...
Solutions Manual for Forecasting For Economics And Business 1st Edition by Gl...
 

More from HELIOSPADILLAMAYER

Seminar Macroeconomic Policy Analysis
Seminar Macroeconomic Policy AnalysisSeminar Macroeconomic Policy Analysis
Seminar Macroeconomic Policy AnalysisHELIOSPADILLAMAYER
 
Managing Organizational Behavior
Managing Organizational BehaviorManaging Organizational Behavior
Managing Organizational BehaviorHELIOSPADILLAMAYER
 
Behavioral Finance Application to Risk
Behavioral Finance Application to RiskBehavioral Finance Application to Risk
Behavioral Finance Application to RiskHELIOSPADILLAMAYER
 
Financial Development and Economic Growth
Financial Development and Economic GrowthFinancial Development and Economic Growth
Financial Development and Economic GrowthHELIOSPADILLAMAYER
 
Systemic Risk Safeguards for Central Clearing Counterparties
Systemic Risk Safeguards for Central Clearing CounterpartiesSystemic Risk Safeguards for Central Clearing Counterparties
Systemic Risk Safeguards for Central Clearing CounterpartiesHELIOSPADILLAMAYER
 
Financial Programming and Oil Dynamics
Financial Programming and  Oil DynamicsFinancial Programming and  Oil Dynamics
Financial Programming and Oil DynamicsHELIOSPADILLAMAYER
 

More from HELIOSPADILLAMAYER (13)

Seminar Macroeconomic Policy Analysis
Seminar Macroeconomic Policy AnalysisSeminar Macroeconomic Policy Analysis
Seminar Macroeconomic Policy Analysis
 
Energy Economics Seminar
Energy Economics SeminarEnergy Economics Seminar
Energy Economics Seminar
 
Managing Organizational Behavior
Managing Organizational BehaviorManaging Organizational Behavior
Managing Organizational Behavior
 
Iceland: Country Risk Profile
Iceland: Country Risk ProfileIceland: Country Risk Profile
Iceland: Country Risk Profile
 
Topics Volatility
Topics VolatilityTopics Volatility
Topics Volatility
 
Behavioral Finance Application to Risk
Behavioral Finance Application to RiskBehavioral Finance Application to Risk
Behavioral Finance Application to Risk
 
Operational Risk
Operational RiskOperational Risk
Operational Risk
 
Financial Development and Economic Growth
Financial Development and Economic GrowthFinancial Development and Economic Growth
Financial Development and Economic Growth
 
Market Risk Management
Market Risk ManagementMarket Risk Management
Market Risk Management
 
Bank Leu Prima Cat Bond Fund
Bank Leu Prima Cat Bond FundBank Leu Prima Cat Bond Fund
Bank Leu Prima Cat Bond Fund
 
Economies in Transition
Economies in TransitionEconomies in Transition
Economies in Transition
 
Systemic Risk Safeguards for Central Clearing Counterparties
Systemic Risk Safeguards for Central Clearing CounterpartiesSystemic Risk Safeguards for Central Clearing Counterparties
Systemic Risk Safeguards for Central Clearing Counterparties
 
Financial Programming and Oil Dynamics
Financial Programming and  Oil DynamicsFinancial Programming and  Oil Dynamics
Financial Programming and Oil Dynamics
 

Recently uploaded

02_Fabio Colombo_Accenture_MeetupDora&Cybersecurity.pptx
02_Fabio Colombo_Accenture_MeetupDora&Cybersecurity.pptx02_Fabio Colombo_Accenture_MeetupDora&Cybersecurity.pptx
02_Fabio Colombo_Accenture_MeetupDora&Cybersecurity.pptxFinTech Belgium
 
Stock Market Brief Deck (Under Pressure).pdf
Stock Market Brief Deck (Under Pressure).pdfStock Market Brief Deck (Under Pressure).pdf
Stock Market Brief Deck (Under Pressure).pdfMichael Silva
 
( Jasmin ) Top VIP Escorts Service Dindigul 💧 7737669865 💧 by Dindigul Call G...
( Jasmin ) Top VIP Escorts Service Dindigul 💧 7737669865 💧 by Dindigul Call G...( Jasmin ) Top VIP Escorts Service Dindigul 💧 7737669865 💧 by Dindigul Call G...
( Jasmin ) Top VIP Escorts Service Dindigul 💧 7737669865 💧 by Dindigul Call G...dipikadinghjn ( Why You Choose Us? ) Escorts
 
Top Rated Pune Call Girls Sinhagad Road ⟟ 6297143586 ⟟ Call Me For Genuine S...
Top Rated  Pune Call Girls Sinhagad Road ⟟ 6297143586 ⟟ Call Me For Genuine S...Top Rated  Pune Call Girls Sinhagad Road ⟟ 6297143586 ⟟ Call Me For Genuine S...
Top Rated Pune Call Girls Sinhagad Road ⟟ 6297143586 ⟟ Call Me For Genuine S...Call Girls in Nagpur High Profile
 
VVIP Pune Call Girls Katraj (7001035870) Pune Escorts Nearby with Complete Sa...
VVIP Pune Call Girls Katraj (7001035870) Pune Escorts Nearby with Complete Sa...VVIP Pune Call Girls Katraj (7001035870) Pune Escorts Nearby with Complete Sa...
VVIP Pune Call Girls Katraj (7001035870) Pune Escorts Nearby with Complete Sa...Call Girls in Nagpur High Profile
 
VIP Independent Call Girls in Mira Bhayandar 🌹 9920725232 ( Call Me ) Mumbai ...
VIP Independent Call Girls in Mira Bhayandar 🌹 9920725232 ( Call Me ) Mumbai ...VIP Independent Call Girls in Mira Bhayandar 🌹 9920725232 ( Call Me ) Mumbai ...
VIP Independent Call Girls in Mira Bhayandar 🌹 9920725232 ( Call Me ) Mumbai ...dipikadinghjn ( Why You Choose Us? ) Escorts
 
The Economic History of the U.S. Lecture 25.pdf
The Economic History of the U.S. Lecture 25.pdfThe Economic History of the U.S. Lecture 25.pdf
The Economic History of the U.S. Lecture 25.pdfGale Pooley
 
06_Joeri Van Speybroek_Dell_MeetupDora&Cybersecurity.pdf
06_Joeri Van Speybroek_Dell_MeetupDora&Cybersecurity.pdf06_Joeri Van Speybroek_Dell_MeetupDora&Cybersecurity.pdf
06_Joeri Van Speybroek_Dell_MeetupDora&Cybersecurity.pdfFinTech Belgium
 
Call Girls Koregaon Park Call Me 7737669865 Budget Friendly No Advance Booking
Call Girls Koregaon Park Call Me 7737669865 Budget Friendly No Advance BookingCall Girls Koregaon Park Call Me 7737669865 Budget Friendly No Advance Booking
Call Girls Koregaon Park Call Me 7737669865 Budget Friendly No Advance Bookingroncy bisnoi
 
00_Main ppt_MeetupDORA&CyberSecurity.pptx
00_Main ppt_MeetupDORA&CyberSecurity.pptx00_Main ppt_MeetupDORA&CyberSecurity.pptx
00_Main ppt_MeetupDORA&CyberSecurity.pptxFinTech Belgium
 
Shrambal_Distributors_Newsletter_Apr-2024 (1).pdf
Shrambal_Distributors_Newsletter_Apr-2024 (1).pdfShrambal_Distributors_Newsletter_Apr-2024 (1).pdf
Shrambal_Distributors_Newsletter_Apr-2024 (1).pdfvikashdidwania1
 
The Economic History of the U.S. Lecture 30.pdf
The Economic History of the U.S. Lecture 30.pdfThe Economic History of the U.S. Lecture 30.pdf
The Economic History of the U.S. Lecture 30.pdfGale Pooley
 
VIP Independent Call Girls in Andheri 🌹 9920725232 ( Call Me ) Mumbai Escorts...
VIP Independent Call Girls in Andheri 🌹 9920725232 ( Call Me ) Mumbai Escorts...VIP Independent Call Girls in Andheri 🌹 9920725232 ( Call Me ) Mumbai Escorts...
VIP Independent Call Girls in Andheri 🌹 9920725232 ( Call Me ) Mumbai Escorts...dipikadinghjn ( Why You Choose Us? ) Escorts
 
The Economic History of the U.S. Lecture 17.pdf
The Economic History of the U.S. Lecture 17.pdfThe Economic History of the U.S. Lecture 17.pdf
The Economic History of the U.S. Lecture 17.pdfGale Pooley
 
Mira Road Awesome 100% Independent Call Girls NUmber-9833754194-Dahisar Inter...
Mira Road Awesome 100% Independent Call Girls NUmber-9833754194-Dahisar Inter...Mira Road Awesome 100% Independent Call Girls NUmber-9833754194-Dahisar Inter...
Mira Road Awesome 100% Independent Call Girls NUmber-9833754194-Dahisar Inter...priyasharma62062
 
VIP Call Girl in Mira Road 💧 9920725232 ( Call Me ) Get A New Crush Everyday ...
VIP Call Girl in Mira Road 💧 9920725232 ( Call Me ) Get A New Crush Everyday ...VIP Call Girl in Mira Road 💧 9920725232 ( Call Me ) Get A New Crush Everyday ...
VIP Call Girl in Mira Road 💧 9920725232 ( Call Me ) Get A New Crush Everyday ...dipikadinghjn ( Why You Choose Us? ) Escorts
 
20240429 Calibre April 2024 Investor Presentation.pdf
20240429 Calibre April 2024 Investor Presentation.pdf20240429 Calibre April 2024 Investor Presentation.pdf
20240429 Calibre April 2024 Investor Presentation.pdfAdnet Communications
 
VIP Call Girl in Mumbai 💧 9920725232 ( Call Me ) Get A New Crush Everyday Wit...
VIP Call Girl in Mumbai 💧 9920725232 ( Call Me ) Get A New Crush Everyday Wit...VIP Call Girl in Mumbai 💧 9920725232 ( Call Me ) Get A New Crush Everyday Wit...
VIP Call Girl in Mumbai 💧 9920725232 ( Call Me ) Get A New Crush Everyday Wit...dipikadinghjn ( Why You Choose Us? ) Escorts
 

Recently uploaded (20)

02_Fabio Colombo_Accenture_MeetupDora&Cybersecurity.pptx
02_Fabio Colombo_Accenture_MeetupDora&Cybersecurity.pptx02_Fabio Colombo_Accenture_MeetupDora&Cybersecurity.pptx
02_Fabio Colombo_Accenture_MeetupDora&Cybersecurity.pptx
 
Stock Market Brief Deck (Under Pressure).pdf
Stock Market Brief Deck (Under Pressure).pdfStock Market Brief Deck (Under Pressure).pdf
Stock Market Brief Deck (Under Pressure).pdf
 
( Jasmin ) Top VIP Escorts Service Dindigul 💧 7737669865 💧 by Dindigul Call G...
( Jasmin ) Top VIP Escorts Service Dindigul 💧 7737669865 💧 by Dindigul Call G...( Jasmin ) Top VIP Escorts Service Dindigul 💧 7737669865 💧 by Dindigul Call G...
( Jasmin ) Top VIP Escorts Service Dindigul 💧 7737669865 💧 by Dindigul Call G...
 
Top Rated Pune Call Girls Sinhagad Road ⟟ 6297143586 ⟟ Call Me For Genuine S...
Top Rated  Pune Call Girls Sinhagad Road ⟟ 6297143586 ⟟ Call Me For Genuine S...Top Rated  Pune Call Girls Sinhagad Road ⟟ 6297143586 ⟟ Call Me For Genuine S...
Top Rated Pune Call Girls Sinhagad Road ⟟ 6297143586 ⟟ Call Me For Genuine S...
 
VVIP Pune Call Girls Katraj (7001035870) Pune Escorts Nearby with Complete Sa...
VVIP Pune Call Girls Katraj (7001035870) Pune Escorts Nearby with Complete Sa...VVIP Pune Call Girls Katraj (7001035870) Pune Escorts Nearby with Complete Sa...
VVIP Pune Call Girls Katraj (7001035870) Pune Escorts Nearby with Complete Sa...
 
VIP Independent Call Girls in Mira Bhayandar 🌹 9920725232 ( Call Me ) Mumbai ...
VIP Independent Call Girls in Mira Bhayandar 🌹 9920725232 ( Call Me ) Mumbai ...VIP Independent Call Girls in Mira Bhayandar 🌹 9920725232 ( Call Me ) Mumbai ...
VIP Independent Call Girls in Mira Bhayandar 🌹 9920725232 ( Call Me ) Mumbai ...
 
The Economic History of the U.S. Lecture 25.pdf
The Economic History of the U.S. Lecture 25.pdfThe Economic History of the U.S. Lecture 25.pdf
The Economic History of the U.S. Lecture 25.pdf
 
06_Joeri Van Speybroek_Dell_MeetupDora&Cybersecurity.pdf
06_Joeri Van Speybroek_Dell_MeetupDora&Cybersecurity.pdf06_Joeri Van Speybroek_Dell_MeetupDora&Cybersecurity.pdf
06_Joeri Van Speybroek_Dell_MeetupDora&Cybersecurity.pdf
 
Call Girls Koregaon Park Call Me 7737669865 Budget Friendly No Advance Booking
Call Girls Koregaon Park Call Me 7737669865 Budget Friendly No Advance BookingCall Girls Koregaon Park Call Me 7737669865 Budget Friendly No Advance Booking
Call Girls Koregaon Park Call Me 7737669865 Budget Friendly No Advance Booking
 
00_Main ppt_MeetupDORA&CyberSecurity.pptx
00_Main ppt_MeetupDORA&CyberSecurity.pptx00_Main ppt_MeetupDORA&CyberSecurity.pptx
00_Main ppt_MeetupDORA&CyberSecurity.pptx
 
Shrambal_Distributors_Newsletter_Apr-2024 (1).pdf
Shrambal_Distributors_Newsletter_Apr-2024 (1).pdfShrambal_Distributors_Newsletter_Apr-2024 (1).pdf
Shrambal_Distributors_Newsletter_Apr-2024 (1).pdf
 
Call Girls in New Ashok Nagar, (delhi) call me [9953056974] escort service 24X7
Call Girls in New Ashok Nagar, (delhi) call me [9953056974] escort service 24X7Call Girls in New Ashok Nagar, (delhi) call me [9953056974] escort service 24X7
Call Girls in New Ashok Nagar, (delhi) call me [9953056974] escort service 24X7
 
The Economic History of the U.S. Lecture 30.pdf
The Economic History of the U.S. Lecture 30.pdfThe Economic History of the U.S. Lecture 30.pdf
The Economic History of the U.S. Lecture 30.pdf
 
VIP Independent Call Girls in Andheri 🌹 9920725232 ( Call Me ) Mumbai Escorts...
VIP Independent Call Girls in Andheri 🌹 9920725232 ( Call Me ) Mumbai Escorts...VIP Independent Call Girls in Andheri 🌹 9920725232 ( Call Me ) Mumbai Escorts...
VIP Independent Call Girls in Andheri 🌹 9920725232 ( Call Me ) Mumbai Escorts...
 
The Economic History of the U.S. Lecture 17.pdf
The Economic History of the U.S. Lecture 17.pdfThe Economic History of the U.S. Lecture 17.pdf
The Economic History of the U.S. Lecture 17.pdf
 
Mira Road Awesome 100% Independent Call Girls NUmber-9833754194-Dahisar Inter...
Mira Road Awesome 100% Independent Call Girls NUmber-9833754194-Dahisar Inter...Mira Road Awesome 100% Independent Call Girls NUmber-9833754194-Dahisar Inter...
Mira Road Awesome 100% Independent Call Girls NUmber-9833754194-Dahisar Inter...
 
(Vedika) Low Rate Call Girls in Pune Call Now 8250077686 Pune Escorts 24x7
(Vedika) Low Rate Call Girls in Pune Call Now 8250077686 Pune Escorts 24x7(Vedika) Low Rate Call Girls in Pune Call Now 8250077686 Pune Escorts 24x7
(Vedika) Low Rate Call Girls in Pune Call Now 8250077686 Pune Escorts 24x7
 
VIP Call Girl in Mira Road 💧 9920725232 ( Call Me ) Get A New Crush Everyday ...
VIP Call Girl in Mira Road 💧 9920725232 ( Call Me ) Get A New Crush Everyday ...VIP Call Girl in Mira Road 💧 9920725232 ( Call Me ) Get A New Crush Everyday ...
VIP Call Girl in Mira Road 💧 9920725232 ( Call Me ) Get A New Crush Everyday ...
 
20240429 Calibre April 2024 Investor Presentation.pdf
20240429 Calibre April 2024 Investor Presentation.pdf20240429 Calibre April 2024 Investor Presentation.pdf
20240429 Calibre April 2024 Investor Presentation.pdf
 
VIP Call Girl in Mumbai 💧 9920725232 ( Call Me ) Get A New Crush Everyday Wit...
VIP Call Girl in Mumbai 💧 9920725232 ( Call Me ) Get A New Crush Everyday Wit...VIP Call Girl in Mumbai 💧 9920725232 ( Call Me ) Get A New Crush Everyday Wit...
VIP Call Girl in Mumbai 💧 9920725232 ( Call Me ) Get A New Crush Everyday Wit...
 

The Relationship between Wage and Inflation

  • 1. The Relationship between Wage and Inflation: Case of Slovenia and Selected Central and Eastern European Countries 1 Helios Padilla Mayer, PhD Government of Republic of Slovenia Institute for Macroeconomic Analysis and Research Gregorčičeva 27,1000 Ljubljana January, 2003 1 hpadillamayer@gmail.com
  • 2. 2 Abstract: In the paper we test the new Phillips curve for Central and Eastern European EU accession countries for the period from 1990 to 2002 and use it to compare the efficiency of the traditional Phillips curve. More specifically, we want to see whether real marginal cost, which includes labor productivity and real wage components, can account for inflation dynamics in the observed sample. Surprisingly, when observing all eight selected countries, the relation between real marginal cost and inflation is opposite than expected. On the other hand, inflation in Baltic States and Slovenia seems to be influenced by real marginal cost. The elasticity coefficient of real wages on inflation for Slovenia shows that inflation was quite responsive to movement in wages during the total period, however, inflation became quite inelastic with respect to wages after 2000. Thus, economic policies that were introduced in Slovenia after 2000 were quite efficient in wage regulation, although the real effect will be observed in a more advanced period.
  • 3. 3 1. Introduction One of the main tasks of the Central Banks of EU accession countries is to achieve price stability and therefore it is really important to determine sources and nature of inflation in this area. Our research targets effects of wages on inflation. Or, more precisely, we try to see whether there is an evidence of wage pressures on inflation. The most conventional model used for testing this relation is the standard Phillips curve approach. However, we follow Gali, Gertler and Lopez-Salido (2001) and test relation between wages and inflation on the basis of so called “new” Phillips curve literature. As the standard Phillips curve, also this one assumes that inflation varies positively with real sector economic activity in the short run. However, the difference is that the new Phillips curve relates inflation to movements in real marginal cost. Thus, real marginal cost is the theoretically appropriate measure of real sector inflationary pressures, as opposed to the cyclical measures used in traditional Phillips curve analysis, such as detrended output and unemployment. One of the advantages of the real marginal cost measure (which in our analysis corresponds to real unit labor cost) is that it directly accounts for the influence of both productivity and wage pressures on inflation. Thus, according to the new Phillips curve theory, productivity, wages and inflation follow the similar path. We want to see whether this relation holds for Central and Eastern European EU accession countries (Czech Republic, Hungary, Estonia, Latvia, Lithuania, Poland, Slovakia and Slovenia). More specifically, we want to test whether wages did have inflationary pressures in Slovenia and if so, what policy measures can be implemented to avoid this effect. In section 2 we first present analyze the connection between inflation and wages on the basis of traditional Phillips curve approach. Then, in section 3 we discuss the new Phillips curve. Section 4 develops the theoretical model used for estimation. Section 5 presents empirical results and draws comparisons between the full country sample and two sub-samples (Baltic States including Slovenia and Central European Countries). Section 6 concludes.
  • 4. 4 2. Traditional Phillips Curve The traditional Phillips curve relates inflation to some cyclical indicator (either level of unemployment of real GDP) and lagged values of inflation. In our analysis, we are going to use the real GDP as the cyclical indicator. Thus, if πt denotes inflation and the log deviation of GDP from its long run trend, then the common specification of the Phillips curve is: , (1) where is a random disturbance. This equation can be understood as a demand-side explanation of inflation; aggregate demand increases following a rise in money supply.2 It is sometimes assumed that the sum of weights on lagged inflation equals to one so that there is no long-run tradeoff between inflation and output. We did not impose this assumption in our analysis because coefficients on lagged inflation variables in the regression equation added up close to one. We run the generalized least squares (GLS) regression controlling for fixed effects3 based on equation (1) for the full country sample, and then (due to their differences) two sub- samples, (a) Central and Eastern European countries, and (b) Baltic States and Slovenia.4 We use quarterly data from 1990 to 2002.5 We run several regressions and the one where we use four lags for inflation fits best the quarterly data. To measure inflation we use log difference of the CPI index, which we obtain from national statistic databases on a quarterly basis. The output term is HP filtered real GDP on a quarterly basis. We also obtain data on quarterly real GDP from national statistic databases. Figure 2.1 shows inflation rate for Slovenia and Central and Eastern European EU candidate countries on a 2 For example, an increase in price level can be caused by a rise in aggregate demand, which is due to an expansionary fiscal policy. 3 Due to heteroskedasticity of data and autocorrelation in the data series, ordinary least square (OLS) estimates are not most efficient, so instead we choose to run the GLS regression and obtain unbiased as well as most efficient coefficients. 4 We also run the regression for Slovenian data only, but since the size and sign of coefficients do not change significantly, we only report regression results on the two sub-samples. 5 We do not include data for first two quarters of 2003 because it is not available for the full country sample. tyˆ tt h i tit y edpgp ++= - = -å 1 1 1 ˆ te
  • 5. 5 yearly basis (average inflation rate).6 Figure 2.2 plots the real GDP growth rates for the same country sample on a yearly basis. The corresponding equation for the full data set is: where standard errors are shown in parentheses. The estimates for the two sub-samples are as follows: (1)  Baltic States with Slovenia (2)  Central European Countries Surprisingly, in all three cases, there is a negative relation between the HP filtered output and current inflation. Coefficients on output for the full sample and a sub-sample for Baltic States and Slovenia are significant at 5 percent level, but the coefficient on Central European countries is not significant. Gali, Gertler and Lopez-Salido (2001) on the other hand show that there was a positive relation between the detrended output and inflation, 6 For the purpose of presentation, inflation rates are expressed in logarithmic form. u_i)toduevarianceof(fraction0.431rho 0.00value-p61.17,statisticF (0.073) yˆ0.129-0.112045.0239.0567.0 (0.951)(0.095)(0.132)(0.137) 1-t4321 = == +-+= ---- ttttt ppppp u_i)toduevarianceof(fraction0.498rho 0.00value-p52.28,statisticF (0.148) yˆ0.376-0.157105.0302.0347.0 (0.172)(0.143)(0.193)(0.219) 1-t4321 = == -++= ---- ttttt ppppp u_i)toduevarianceof(fraction0.109rho 0.00value-p12.84,statisticF (0.667) yˆ0.026-0.161046.0044.0618.0 (0.093)(0.115)(0.160)(0.145) 1-t4321 = == +-+= ---- ttttt ppppp
  • 6. 6 which actually corresponds to the real essence of the traditional Phillips curve. Thus, the traditional Phillips curve is not really able to explain the stability of relation between inflation and output over the observed period nor account for the policy reforms that were introduced in these countries in order to suppress inflation. Moreover, coefficients on lagged inflation may very well embed expectations of future inflation. Hence, it is necessary to remodel the traditional Phillips curve in order to observe the whether inflation can be better explained through the supply side of the economy. 3. The New Phillips Curve The new Phillips curve is based on staggered nominal price setting (Taylor, 1980). The price setting behavior is based on optimization by monopolistically competitive firms. The basic equation that we are going to test is the one that relates inflation πt to the anticipated future inflation πt+1 and real marginal cost: (2) where is the average real marginal cost, in percent deviation from its steady state level, β is subjective discount factor, and λ is the slope coefficient that depends on the parameters of the model. This equation shows direct effects of the frictions in the price adjustment process that are the key aspects of the theory (Gali,Gertler,Lopez-Salido, 2001). Nevertheless, the new Phillips curve literature (Goodfriend and King, 1997) relates inflation to an output gap variable.7 Assuming restrictions on technology and labor market structure, real marginal cost are proportionally related to the output gap (Rotemberg and Woodford, 1997), , (3) ( ) tttt ME ˆ 1 lpbp += + tMˆ )(ˆ * ttt yyM -= d
  • 7. 7 where are the logarithms of real output and the natural level of real output, respectively. Combining equations (2) and (3) results in the standard output gap based for relations of the new Phillips curve. , (4) where . However, in the literature equation (4) has been the subject of a considerable discussion. According to the traditional Phillips curve, inflation varies positively with the output gap. On the other hand, in the new Phillips curve context, inflation is an entirely forward- looking phenomenon. By iterating equation (4) forward we get: , (5) This equation shows that if a central bank can commit to stabilizing the output gap , it can reach price stability. On the other side this equation also suggest that inflation should anticipate movements in the output gap. So far, as the approximation of the traditional Phillips curve recommend, the output gap tends to lead inflation. Gali, Gertler, and Lopez-Salido, 2001, Sbordone, 1999, and Gali and Gertler, 1999 have shown that this relation holds for the US as well as for the EU countries. Thus, the output gap formulation of the new Phillips curve cannot account for the persistence of inflation either for the US or the EU countries. Nevertheless, above mention authors find that the relation between inflation and real marginal cost given by equation (2) is some how consistent with the data. Thus, the link between the real marginal cost and the output gap corresponds with data. It seems that 7 For a detailed discussion on output gap refer to Bovha Padilla and Padilla Mayer, 2002. * and tt yy ( ) )( * 1 ttttt yykE -+= +pbp ld=k )( * 0 ktktt k k t yyEk ++ ¥ = -= åbp )( * ktkt yy ++ -
  • 8. 8 real marginal cost response sluggishly to output gap movements, the same way as inflation does. The first possible explanation for that is that conventional measures of the output gap are not adequate. It may not be appropriate to use detrended output to estimate the output gap if there are significant real shocks to the economy. The second explanation could be that there are rigidities in the labor market (either in the form of real or nominal wage rigidities), which break down the relation between marginal cost and output gap (equation 3). These rigidities offer an explanation for inactive behavior of real marginal cost. 4. The Baseline Model In this section we present relation between inflation and real marginal cost across firms. As Gali, Gertler and Lopez-Salido, 2001, we assume that firms face increasing real marginal cost.8 We assume that there is a continuum of firms indexed by . Each firm is a monopolistic competitor, it produces a differentiated good , and sells it at nominal price . The demand curve that each firm faces is then , where and are aggregate output and aggregate price, respectively. The production function for firm is given by , where is a technological parameter, is employment, and a is the share of labor in income. Firms set nominal prices on a reel basis as in Calvo, 1983. Each firm resets its price with probability each period, while a fraction of producers leave their prices unchanged. Thus, the expected time that the price remains fixed is and the parameter then shows the degree of price rigidity. [ ]1,0Îj ( )jYt ( )jPt ( ) ( ) t t t t Y P jP jY e- ÷÷ ø ö çç è æ = tY tP j ( ) ( ) a- = 1 jLAjY ttt tA ( )jLt q-1 q q-1 1 q
  • 9. 9 The price level can be expressed as a function of the newly set price and the lagged price .9 (6) All firms that change price in period choose the same value of . A firm that is able to reset price in period chooses price to maximize expected discounted profits given technology, factor prices and the constraint on price adjustment (defined by the reset probability ). An optimizing firm will set according to the following log-linear rule: , (7) where is a discount factor, is the logarithm of nominal marginal cost in period of a firm that last reset its price in period , and is the firm´s desired gross markup. We need to find an expression for inflation in terms of an observable measure of aggregate marginal cost. By cost minimizing rule the firm´s real marginal cost equals the real wage divided by the marginal product of labor. Given the Cobb-Douglass production function, the real marginal cost is given by , where and are output and employment for a firm that has set price in at the 8 Allowing marginal cost to vary across firms gives more reliable estimates of the degree of price rigidity in the Euro area as showing in Gali, Gertler and Lopez-Salido, 2001. 9 This expression is obtained after log-linearizing the price index around zero inflation steady state and it is taken in a log form. tp * tp 1-tp 1 * )1( -+-= ttt ppp qq t * tp t q-1 * tp ( ) ( ) ( )n kttt k k t MEp + ¥ = å-+= , 0 * 1log bqbqµ b ( )n kttM +, kt + t 1- = e e µ ( ) ( )( )kttktt ktkt ktt LY PW M ++ ++ + - = ,, , /1 / a kttY +, kttL +, t
  • 10. 10 optimal value . Since we cannot observe individual firm marginal cost (absence of firm level data), we define “average” marginal cost, which depends only on aggregates: (8) By exploiting the assumptions of Cobb-Douglas production function and isoelastic demand curve, we obtain the following log-linear relation between and : (9) where and are the log deviations of and from their respective steady state values. We obtain the formulation of the new Phillips curve that relates inflation to the real marginal cost by combining equations (6), (7), and (9), , where (10) (11) Slope of the coefficient depends of parameters of the model. is decreasing in the degree of price rigidity, , which shows the fraction of firms that keep their prices constant. Thus, the smaller the fraction of firms that adjust prices, the less sensitive inflation will be to movements in marginal cost. Moreover, is also decreasing in the slope of production function, measured by , and in the elasticity of demand, . The larger and , the more sensitive is the marginal cost of an individual firm to deviations of its price from the average price level. Finally, the model suggests that inflation should equal a discounted stream of expected future average real marginal costs. * tP ( ) ( )( )tt tt t LY PW M /1 / a- = kttM +, tM )( 1 ˆˆ * , kttktktt ppMM +++ - - -= a ea kttM +, ˆ ktM + ˆ kttM +, tM ( ) tttt ME ˆ 1 lpbp += + [ ])1(1 )1)(1)(1( -+ --- = eaq abqq l l l q l a e a e
  • 11. 11 5. Empirical Results In this section we present estimates of the baseline model (equation 10) for the sample of selected EU candidate countries. Since we are interested to observe whether Slovenia follows the full sample, we also perform analysis of Slovenia inflation dynamics separately. We use quarterly data from 1990 to 2002.10 Data for inflation and real GDP are obtained from the Countries in Transition CD-Rom (on a yearly basis), WIIW, and quarterly series are obtained from the national statistical offices. Inflation is given as a percentage change in prices with respect to the previous year, and the real GDP data are given in 1995 prices. We calculate average real marginal cost (equation 8) in the following way. First, we obtain data on gross monthly real wages per capita, quarterly data on real GDP and labor force. Since we calculate quarterly marginal cost, we set up the nominator as a sum of the three month gross real wages per capita. We also need data on labor income share, which we calculate according to Dobrinsky (2001). He presented a measure of capital income share for countries in transition. According to him, the capital income share can be calculated as the share of gross operating surplus and gross mixed income compared to total factor incomes.11 Thus, the labor income share is simply calculated as a share of compensation of employees compared to total factor incomes. Since we cannot obtain quarterly data on compensation of employees and total factor income, we use yearly data and therefore calculate labor income share on a yearly basis. However, we believe that this share is not varying significantly during the year and we use it for calculating quarterly real average marginal cost. Thus, the denominator is calculated as a product of annual labor income share and ratio of a real GDP and labor force on a quarterly basis. Then, we use the log deviation of real marginal cost from its mean as a measure of . 10 We do not include data for first two quarters of 2003 because it is not available for the full country sample. 11 Total factor incomes can be calculated as the difference between the nominal GDP and net indirect taxes. tMˆ
  • 12. 12 Figures 5.1 and 5.2 show our measure of real marginal costs along with inflation for Central and Eastern European EU Candidate Countries. Surprisingly, when we take into account the full sample, variables do not move closely together. Although correlation between inflation and real marginal costs is positive, it is extremely small and non- significant. Thus, it is hard to say that inflation is really related to movements in marginal costs as suggested by the theory explained in Section 4. Moreover, Table 5.1 shows correlation between inflation and real marginal cost for all countries that are in the sample. Inflation could be best explained by variation in real marginal cost in Baltic region (Estonia, Latvia and Lithuania). Correlation between both variables is relatively high also for Slovenia. Moreover, elasticity coefficient for Slovenia shows that inflation is relatively responsive on real wages. Increasing wages by 1 percent would increase inflation by 2.76 percent. Thus, according to the real data from the observed period, wages did have inflationary pressures in Slovenia. On the other hand, there is strong negative correlation between inflation and real marginal cost in Poland, Czech Republic, Slovakia and Hungary. Table 5.1: Correlation between Real Marginal Cost and Inflation We then present empirical estimates of coefficients in equation (9). First, we present estimates of the baseline model for the full sample, and then for two sub-samples: (1) Country Correlation Czech Republic -0.73 Estonia 0.73 Hungary -0.06 Latvia 0.66 Lithuania 0.63 Poland -0.83 Slovakia -0.55 Slovenia 0.52 Average 0.04
  • 13. 13 Baltic States with Slovenia, and (2) Central European countries. We show that in contrast with findings for the Euro area and the USA (Gali, Gertler, Lopez-Salido, 2001) this model does not explain the dynamics of inflation in the Central and Eastern European EU candidate countries in expected way. 5.1. Baseline Model Estimates We estimate the coefficients in equation (9) by using generalized method of moments (GMM). Under rational expectations, equation (9) defines the set of orthogonality conditions: , where zt denotes a vector of variables observed in time t, that is, instrumental variables. The optimal choice of instrumental variables are lags of explanatory variables already presented in the model: lags of inflation, lags of real marginal cost and detrended output. Since the data series consists only from 52 observations (per country), we choose relatively small number of lags for instruments in order to minimize the potential estimation bias that can arise in small samples. As Gali, Gertler and Lopez-Salido, 2001, we use four lags of inflation, two lags of the real marginal costs, and detrended output.12 The corresponding equation for the full data set is: where standard errors are shown in parentheses. The estimates for the two sub-samples13 are as follows: 12 We tried to estimate coefficients with using more than four lags for inflation and more than two lags for the real marginal costs, but results were not affected. ( )( ) 01 =-- + ttttt zmcE lbpp 0.01value-p5.24,statisticJ 0.00value-p16.20,statisticFˆ271.4)(2215.0 (1.132)(0.073) 1 == ==-= + tttt ME pp
  • 14. 14 (1)  Baltic States with Slovenia (2)  Central European Countries In all three equations, standard errors are modified using a Newey-West correction to account for serial correlation in the error terms. Also, we take care of fixed effects in all three regressions. In order to check for potential weakness of the instruments, we perform an F-test applied to the first stage regression. Results show that instruments that we use are relevant (see F statistic in above regressions). We also test for overidentifying restrictions of the model.14 On the basis of Hansen test, we reject overidentifying restrictions for all three regressions (see J statistic in above regression). In general, the empirical model does not work as expected in the full sample and in the sub-sample of Central European countries (Czech Republic, Slovakia, Poland). The coefficients on marginal cost are negative and significant at 5 percent level in both cases. The only case that coefficient is positive and significant as implied by the theory is in the case of Baltic States including Slovenia. This result is in contrast with findings of Gali, Gertler, and Lopez-Salido, 2001, where they estimate positive and highly significant effect of marginal cost on inflation in the Euro area and the USA.15 13 Again, we run an individual regression analysis for Slovenia, but since the size and significance of coefficients do not change, we report results only on the two sub-samples. 14 The model is overidentified is there is more than one way to calculate its parameters from the reduced form parameters, leading to restrictions on the reduced form parameters. 15 However, we need to take into the account that the findings for the Euro are and the USA are based on the quarterly data set from 1970 to 1998. After that time there has been a decline in unemployment and a J(1.738)(0.103) 0.01value-p4.22,statistic 0.00value-p13.73,statisticFˆ649.3)(314.0 1 == ==+= + tttt ME pp J(0.772)(0.082) 0.01value-p4.65,statistic 0.00value-p18.65,statisticFˆ695.3)(178.0 1 == ==-= + tttt ME pp
  • 15. 15 6. Final Remarks Our results indicate that neither traditional nor a marginal cost-based Phillips curves do not provide a satisfactory explanation of Central and Eastern European area inflation from 1990 to 2002. First, due to policy reforms that were oriented toward reduction of inflation in the post transition period, the traditional Phillips curve did not show the positive relation between the output and price level neither in the full sample nor in the two sub-samples. The new Phillips curve model suggests that marginal cost is negatively related to inflation for the full sample. On the other hand, results for Baltic States and Slovenia are in accordance with the model prediction. According to this information, wages in Slovenia did have inflationary pressures. However, one should be aware that this result is obtained on the basis of quarterly data from 1990 to 2002. Since 2000 there have been wage policies introduced which allowed the increase of wages only with respect to an increase in productivity and thus should not have inflationary pressures. Indeed, if one checks the elasticity of wages with respect to inflation on the basis of data from 2000 on, the coefficient drops to 0.67 percent (with respect to 2.76 percent when full period data is taken into account). However, if one runs the regression on the basis of the new Phillips curve with the data from 2000 on, results do not change: there is still positive and significant relation between real marginal cost and inflation. Therefore, at this point it is hard to say how marginal cost really affects inflation dynamics and thus give more precise policy recommendations. It would be appropriate to decompose the movement in real marginal cost in order to isolate the factors that drive this variable. One possible decomposition is into a component that accounts for labor market frictions (measured as the wage markup) and the other one that would correspond to the frictionless competitive equilibrium. rise in the output growth in the Euro area, without any corresponding rise in inflation. Thus, including more recent period in the analysis of Euro inflation dynamics may alter results.
  • 16. 16 Moreover, to determine whether wages really have inflationary pressures on selected countries in the observed sample, it is necessary to understand the determinants of the wage markup. Nevertheless, it will be necessary to include in the analysis additional factors, such as union pressures, that would account for variation in the wage markup and thus explain its effect on inflation dynamics of Central and Eastern European EU candidate countries. 7. References 1.   Bovha Padilla, S. and H. Padilla Mayer, 2002. “Sources of GDP Growth, Potential Output and Output Gap for Slovenia: Mid-Term Analysis”, IB Review, Institute for Macroeconomic Analysis and Development, Ljubljana, Slovenia, June 2002. 2.   Bovha Padilla, S. and H. Padilla Mayer, 2002. “Sources of Growth in Selected Central and Eastern European Countries”, Countries in Transition International Conference, Kranjska Gora, Slovenia, June 2003. 3.   Calvo, G., 1983. “Staggered Prices in a Utility Maximizing Framework”, Journal of Monetary Economics, 12, 383-398. 4.   Eurostat, 1997-2003. “Statistical Information”, various issues. 5.   Eurostat, 1997-2002. “Statistical Yearbook for Central and Eastern European Countries”, various issues. 6.   Gali, J. and M. Gertler, 1999. “Inflation Dynamics: A Structural Econometric Analysis”, Journal of Monetary Economics, 44, 195-222. 7.   Gali, J., M. Gertler and J. Lopez-Salido, 2001. “European Inflation Dynamics”, NBER Working Paper Series, Working Paper 8218, 39 pp. 8.   Goodfriend, M. and R. King, 1997. “The New Neoclassical Synthesis”, in NBER Macroeconomic Annual, Ben Bernanke and Julio Rotemberg, eds., MIT Press. 9.   Intriligator, M., R. Bodkin, and C, Hsiao, 1978. “Econometric Models, Techniques and Applications”, Prentice Hall, Upper Saddle River, NJ. 10.  Rotemberg, J. and M. Woodford, 1997. “An Optimization-based Economic Framework for the Evaluation of Monetary Policy”, in NBER Macroeconomic Annual, Ben Bernanke and Julio Rotemberg, eds., MIT Press. 11.  Sbordone, A., 1999. “Prices and Unit Labor Costs: A New Test of Price Stickiness”, mimeo, Rutgers University. 12.  Taylor, J., 1980. “Aggregate Dynamics and Staggered Contracts”, Journal of Monetary Economics, 44, 293-335. 13.  WIIW: Countries in Transition 2002, CD-Rom.
  • 17. 17 Figure 2.1: Inflation in Slovenia and Central and Eastern European EU Candidate Countries from 1990 to 2002 (log form) Source: Countries in Transition 2002, WIIW, Eurostat, selected publications. Figure 2.2: Real GDP Growth Rates in Slovenia and Central and Eastern European EU Candidate Countries from 1990 to 2002, in percent Source: Countries in Transition 2002, WIIW, Eurostat, selected publications. -­5.5 3.22.9 4.6 5.2 3.8 4.6 3.5 4.1 5.3 2.8 -­8.9 -­4.7 -­12 -­10 -­8 -­6 -­4 -­2 0 2 4 6 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 in  % Slovenia Average 1.97 2.132.19 1.81 2.07 2.12 2.29 2.60 3.04 3.49 5.33 4.74 6.31 1.5 2 2.5 3 3.5 4 4.5 5 5.5 6 6.5 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 ln  Inflation Average Slovenia
  • 18. 18 Figure 5.1: Inflation and Real Marginal Cost in Central and Eastern European EU Candidate Countries* * Data are in logarithmic forms. Left-side scale measures inflation and the right-side scale measures real marginal costs as explained in Sections 3 and 4. Source: Authors´calculations. Figure 5.2: Inflation and Real Marginal Cost in Central and Eastern European EU Candidate Countries* a)   Czech Republic 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 -­0.04 -­0.02 0 0.02 0.04 0.06 0.08 Inflation Real  Marginal  Cost 0 0.5 1 1.5 2 2.5 3 3.5 4 4.5 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 -­0.5 -­0.4 -­0.3 -­0.2 -­0.1 0 0.1 0.2 Inflation Real  Marginal  Cost
  • 19. 19 b)   Estonia c)   Hungary 0 0.5 1 1.5 2 2.5 3 3.5 4 4.5 5 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 -­0.1 -­0.05 0 0.05 0.1 0.15 0.2 Inflation Real  Marginal  Cost 0 0.5 1 1.5 2 2.5 3 3.5 4 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 -­0.1 -­0.05 0 0.05 0.1 0.15 Inflation Real  Marginal  Cost
  • 20. 20 d)   Latvia e)   Lithuania 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 -­0.25 -­0.2 -­0.15 -­0.1 -­0.05 0 0.05 0.1 0.15 Inflation Real  Marginal  Cost -­2 -­1 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 -­0.2 -­0.1 0 0.1 0.2 0.3 0.4 Inflation Real  Marginal  Cost
  • 21. 21 f)   Poland g)   Slovak Republic 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 -­0.4 -­0.3 -­0.2 -­0.1 0 0.1 0.2 0.3 Inflation Real  Marginal  Cost 0 0.5 1 1.5 2 2.5 3 3.5 4 4.5 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 -­0.2 -­0.15 -­0.1 -­0.05 0 0.05 0.1 0.15 0.2 0.25 0.3 Inflation Real  Marginal  Cost
  • 22. 22 h)   Slovenia * Data are in logarithmic forms. Left-side scale measures inflation and the right side scale measures real marginal costs as explained in Sections 3 and 4. Source: Authors´calculations. 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 -­0.08 -­0.06 -­0.04 -­0.02 0 0.02 0.04 0.06 Inflation Real  Marginal  Cost