SlideShare a Scribd company logo
1 of 23
Download to read offline
The Unproductive Housewife: Her Evolution in Nineteenth-Century Economic Thought
Author(s): Nancy Folbre
Source: Signs, Vol. 16, No. 3 (Spring, 1991), pp. 463-484
Published by: The University of Chicago Press
Stable URL: http://www.jstor.org/stable/3174585
Accessed: 28-05-2017 11:03 UTC
REFERENCES
Linked references are available on JSTOR for this article:
http://www.jstor.org/stable/3174585?seq=1&cid=pdf-reference#references_tab_contents
You may need to log in to JSTOR to access the linked references.
JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide range of content in a trusted
digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and facilitate new forms of scholarship. For more information about
JSTOR, please contact support@jstor.org.
Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available at
http://about.jstor.org/terms
The University of Chicago Press is collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend access to
Signs
This content downloaded from 154.59.124.94 on Sun, 28 May 2017 11:03:11 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
THE UNPRODUCTIVE HOUSEWIFE:
HER EVOLUTION IN NINETEENTH-
CENTURY ECONOMIC THOUGHT
NANCY FOLBRE
In 1878 the officers of the Association for the Advancement of
Women (AAW) protested the U.S. Census's notion that "home-
keepers" were not gainful workers. In a letter to Congress they
wrote, "We pray your honorable body to make provision for the
more careful and just enumeration of women as laborers and
producers." They complained that women's domestic efforts were
"not even incidentally named as in any wise affecting the causes of
increase or decrease of population or wealth."' (See Appendix.) In
short, the AAW quarreled with the official assumption that house-
wives were unproductive workers because they earned no pay.
Census data consist of ordered sets of numbers. They appear
objective and value free, but their meaning grows out of socially
constructed concepts that are laden with cultural and political
values. "Statistical reports exemplify the process by which visions
My collaboration with Marjorie Abel on related topics inspired this article;
Margo Anderson kept me going. Daniel Scott Smith provided many helpful
suggestions, including one that led me to the expertise of archivist Susan Grigg,
director of the Sophia Smith Collection at Smith College. David Alexander, Donald
McCloskey, and Robert Solow offered invaluable encouragement. Two anonymous
reviewers of Signs suggested important revisions in the exposition of the arguments.
Thanks to all.
Memorial of Mary F. Eastman, Henrietta L. T. Woolcott, and others ... Senate
Miscellaneous Documents, 45th Congress, 2d Session, vol. 2, no. 84 (Serial Set,
1786). For full text, see Appendix.
[Signs: Journal of Women in Culture and Society 1991, vol. 16, no. 3]
? 1991 by The University of Chicago. All rights reserved. 0097-9740/91/1603-0002$01.00
463
This content downloaded from 154.59.124.94 on Sun, 28 May 2017 11:03:11 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
Folbre / UNPRODUCTIVE HOUSEWIFE
of reality, models of social structure, were elaborated and revised,"
writes Joan Scott.2 Other recent feminist scholarship details the
androcentric focus of many conventional census categories.3
Gender bias in the definition of economically productive activity
has important implications for the analysis of changes in female
labor-force participation. One aspect of such gender bias-the con-
cept of the unproductive housewife-gradually coalesced in the
nineteenth-century censuses of population in England and the
United States. In 1800, women whose work consisted largely of
caring for their families were considered productive workers. By
1900, they had been formally relegated to the census category of
"dependents," a category that included infants, young children, the
sick, and the elderly.
Several factors shaped the changing attitudes toward household
labor during the nineteenth century. A new enthusiasm for female
domesticity soothed apprehensions about the impact of capitalist
development on the family, and the growth of paid domestic service
relieved upper-class women from the most onerous domestic
chores. But gender interests were also influential. When male trade
unionists argued that hardworking housewives were-or should
be-"dependents," they obscured the benefits men enjoyed from
women's domestic labor.
Political economists and statisticians played an important role in
the deployment of a new vocabulary that complemented the
idealization of family life and men's demands for a family wage.
While they seldom explicitly discussed household labor, they
addressed related topics, and their influence on official terminology
can be traced through the evolution of census categories. In Great
Britain, the initial assumption that housewives were gainful work-
ers was gradually displaced, with the assistance of economist Alfred
Marshall. The prominent Francis Amasa Walker, who took charge of
the U.S. census after the Civil War, ignored the productive contri-
butions of housewives, despite strong feminist criticisms. In Mas-
sachusetts, the liberal Carroll Wright encouraged attention to
2 Joan Scott, "A Statistical Representation of Work," in her Gender and History
(New York: Columbia University Press, 1988), 113-38, esp. 115.
3 In addition to Scott, see Desley Deacon, "Political Arithmetic: The Nineteenth
Century Australian Census and the Construction of the Dependent Woman," Signs:
Journal of Women in Culture and Society 11, no. 1 (Autumn 1985): 27-47; Margo
Anderson, The American Census: A Social History (New Haven, Conn.: Yale
University Press, 1988); Marilyn Waring, If Women Counted: A New Feminist
Economics (New York: Harper & Row, 1988); Nancy Folbre and Marjorie Abel,
"Women's Work and Women's Households: Gender Bias in the U.S. Census," Social
Research 56, no. 3 (Autumn 1989): 545-70.
464
This content downloaded from 154.59.124.94 on Sun, 28 May 2017 11:03:11 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
Spring 1991 / SIGNS
household work, but the census in his state gradually, if reluctantly,
relinquished the concept of the productive housewife.
Domesticity and devaluation
Praise of domesticity and the unique character of the family home
played a widely recognized role in nineteenth-century social
thought. The "cult of domesticity" contributed to the emergence of
a distinctively female culture and became an important strand of
nineteenth-century feminism. While feminist scholarship has fo-
cused on the social and cultural aspects of this phenomenon, the
economic implications have been largely ignored.4
Ironically, the moral elevation of the home was accompanied by
the economic devaluation of the work performed there. The growth
of wage labor, which separated individuals from traditional family-
based productive units, almost inevitably wrought new concepts of
productive labor. Goods that could be bought and sold, quantities
that could be expressed in dollar terms, became the new arbiters of
value. Indeed, the growing enthusiasm for social statistics, re-
flected in new census-taking efforts, deflected attention from activ-
ities that could not easily be reduced to a money metric.
Over the course of the nineteenth century, work once performed
within patriarchal households under the authority of fathers and
husbands was gradually, but only partially, supplanted by the
growth of an impersonal marketplace in which the labor power of
individuals was bought and sold like any other commodity. Single
women entered the paid labor force in large numbers, but most left
upon marriage. As late as 1900, 40 percent of single women, but
only 6 percent of married women, over age ten in the United States
were designated "occupied" by the U.S. Census. In England and
Wales in 1901, about 10 percent of married women were listed with
occupations.5
These figures understate the contributions that women made to
their families' economic welfare. Numerous social historical stud-
ies show that married women not only performed domestic labor
4 Barbara Welter, "The Cult of True Womanhood," American Quarterly 18, no. 2
(1966): 151-74; Linda Kerber, "Separate Spheres, Female Worlds, Woman's Place:
The Rhetoric of Women's History," Journal of American History 75, no. 1 (June
1988): 9-39.
5 Twelfth Census of the United States: 1900, Special Reports, Supplementary
Analysis and Derivative Tables (Washington, D.C.: Government Printing Office);
Census of England and Wales, 1901.
465
This content downloaded from 154.59.124.94 on Sun, 28 May 2017 11:03:11 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
Folbre / UNPRODUCTIVE HOUSEWIFE
but also garnered significant amounts of market income.6 The wives of
farmers, merchants, and craftsmen participated in family enterprises.
Many women took in boarders and lodgers, exchanging household
services such as cooking and cleaning for money. Housewives pro-
vided their own families with an even wider range of domestic
services-meal preparation, laundry, child rearing, care of the sick and
elderly, household management, and general nurturance.
During the late eighteenth and early nineteenth centuries,
domestic work was recognized as a productive and valuable con-
tribution. Despite a strict sexual division of labor, many men as well
as women produced goods and services for household use, includ-
ing housing, furniture, and food grown for the family table. As male
participation in the market economy expanded, however, produc-
tion for use rather than exchange became identified as a distinctly
female activity.7 The home was often described in feminine terms-
stable, reassuring, altruistic. The market, by contrast, was a mascu-
line, dynamic realm, characterized by competition and the pursuit
of economic self-interest.
A new emphasis on domestic virtue, rather than domestic work,
was rooted in genuine fears about the impact of a new emphasis on
profits and personal gain that conflicted with traditional religious
values. Catherine Beecher's Treatise on Domestic Economy, first
published in 1841, strictly banished the logic of economic self-
interest and laissez-faire from the home. The great mission of the
"family state," she wrote, "is self denial and in training its members
to self-sacrificing labors for the ignorant and weak."8 Beecher
consistently argued that women's allegiance to home and family
was a necessary counterbalance to the competitive anarchy of the
market economy.9
6 Alice Clark, Working Life of Women in the Seventeenth Century (1919; reprint,
New York: Kelley, 1967); Edith Abbott, Women in Industry: A Study in American
Economic History (1910; reprint, New York: Appleton, 1924); Joan Jensen, Loosen-
ing the Bonds: Mid-Atlantic Farm Women, 1750-1850 (New Haven, Conn.: Yale
University Press, 1986); Claudia Goldin, "The Female Labor Force and American
Economic Growth, 1890-1980," in Long-Term Factors in American Economic
Growth, ed. Stanley L. Engerman and Robert E. Gallman, National Bureau of
Economic Research Studies in Income and Wealth, vol. 51 (Chicago: University of
Chicago Press, 1986), 557-604.
7 Glenna Matthews, Just a Housewife: The Rise and Fall of Domesticity in
America (New York: Oxford University Press, 1987); Ruth Schwartz Cowan, More
Workfor Mother: The Ironies of Household Technologyfrom the Open Hearth to the
Microwave (New York: Basic, 1983).
8 Catherine Beecher, A Treatise on Domestic Economy (1841; reprint, New York:
Source Book Press, 1974), 19.
9 Kathryn Kish Sklar, Catherine Beecher: A Study in American Domesticity (New
York: Norton, 1976).
466
This content downloaded from 154.59.124.94 on Sun, 28 May 2017 11:03:11 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
Spring 1991 / SIGNS
She developed her philosophy further in The American Wom-
an's Home, published in 1869 and coauthored with her sister,
Harriet Beecher Stowe.?' The book embodies the contradictory
character of Victorian domesticity. On the one hand, it provides a
wealth of technical details regarding the efficient management and
performance of household labor. On the other hand, it treats this
work as a moral responsibility, not an economically important
activity that might be organized along different, less gendered
lines. This was family labor, not domestic labor-its aim, the
fulfillment of God-given responsibilities, not economic efficiency;
its motive not self-interest, but love.
Most political economists reinforced this distinction between
the moral (or private) and the economic (or public) world, neatly
assigning women and the family to one, men and the market to the
other." Even the prominent English neoclassicals, well known for
their emphasis on the competitive marketplace, were reluctant to
allow economic self-interest to disrupt the home. Stanley Jevons,
an otherwise loyal advocate of laissez-faire, proposed that mothers
with children under age three should be banned from factories and
workshops.'2 Alfred Marshall cautioned against increases in wom-
en's wages that might tempt wives and mothers to neglect their
household duties.l3
Growing class differences also contributed to a new view of
married women's roles. The "lady," long the ideal of English
aristocratic society, began to supplant the housewife as a cultural
ideal in the United States during the 1830s.14 With the increased
availability of domestic servants, middle- and upper-class families
redefined the role of wives, emphasizing their qualities of personal
nurturance and their civilizing influence on husbands and children.
By 1880, more than fifteen domestic servants were enumerated per
100 families in many major cities.'5
10 Catherine Beecher and Harriet Beecher Stowe, The American Woman's Home
(New York: J. B. Ford, 1869).
" Nancy Folbre and Heidi Hartmann, "The Rhetoric of SelfInterest and the Ideology
of Gender," in The Consequences of Economic Rhetoric, ed. Arjo Klamer, Donald Mc-
Closkey, and Robert Solow (New York: Cambridge University Press, 1988), 184-206.
12 Stanley Jevons, "Married Women in Factories," in Methods of Social Reform
and Other Papers (London: Macmillan, 1883).
"3 Alfred Marshall, Principles of Economics, 8th ed. (London: Macmillan, 1930:
685, 715.
14 Sarah Eisenstein, Give Us Bread but Give Us Roses: Working Women's
Consciousness in the United States, 1890 to the First World War (Boston: Routledge
& Kegan Paul, 1983).
15 David Katzman, Seven Days a Week: Women and Domestic Service in Indus-
trial America (New York: Oxford University Press, 1978), 286. See also Faye
467
This content downloaded from 154.59.124.94 on Sun, 28 May 2017 11:03:11 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
Folbre / UNPRODUCTIVE HOUSEWIFE
Victorian culture promoted new, refined ideals that working-
class women, busy keeping their families fed and clothed, could
seldom afford.16 Yet these ideals proved appealing partly because
they helped stabilize a traditional patriarchal system that was being
shaken by women's new economic opportunities outside the home.
Wally Seccombe persuasively describes the emergence of the
"male breadwinner norm" in England as an expression of the
economic interests of skilled male trade unionists who feared
competition from women who would work for a lower wage.'7 Me
also benefited economically from the cheap domestic services t
women provided for them in the home.'8
In both England and the United States, predominantly ma
trade unions couched their demands in terms of a "family wa
that only men should earn.'9 Economic vocabulary played
important part in such arguments. Consider the words of a memb
of the National Typographer's Union who protested the seating
Susan B. Anthony at a National Labor Union Conference in 186
"The lady goes in for taking women away from the wash tub, and
the name of heaven, who is going there, if they don't? I believe in
a woman's doing her work, men marrying them and support
them."20 The gentleman's concern with his laundry hints at t
stake men had in reinforcing women's domestic responsibilitie
self-interest that this speaker obscured with the concept of m
economic "support." When male trade unionists argued that th
should earn enough money so their wives would not have to wo
Dudden, Household Service in Nineteenth-Century America (Middletown, Co
Wesleyan University Press, 1983); and Theresa McBride, The Domestic Revolut
The Modernization of Household Service in England and France, 1820-1920 (N
York: Holmes & Meier, 1976).
16 Gerda Lerner, "The Lady and the Mill Girl: Changes in the Status of Wom
in the Age of Jackson," Midcontinent American Studies Journal 10, no. 1 (Spr
1969): 5-15.
17 Wally Seccombe, "Patriarchy Stabilized: The Construction of the Male Bre
winner Wage Norm in Nineteenth-Century Britain," Social History 2, no. 1 (Janua
1986): 53-76.
18 Heidi Hartmann, "Capitalism, Patriarchy, and Job Segregation by Sex," Signs 1,
no. 3 (Spring 1976): 137-69; Phillip Foner, Women and the American Labor
Movement: From Colonial Times to the Eve of World War I (New York: Free Press,
1979); Sonia Rose, "Gender and Work: Sex, Class and Industrial Capitalism,"
History Workshop Journal 21 (Spring 1986): 557-604; Sidney Webb, "Women's
Wages," in Problems of Modern Industry, by Sidney Webb and Beatrice Webb (New
York: Longmans Green, 1989), 46-81.
19 Martha May, "Bread before Roses: American Workingmen, Labor Unions and
the Family Wage," in Women, Work and Protest: A Century of U.S. Women's Labor
History, ed. Ruth Milkman (Boston: Routledge & Kegan Paul, 1985), 113-31.
20 Foner, 136.
468
This content downloaded from 154.59.124.94 on Sun, 28 May 2017 11:03:11 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
Spring 1991 / SIGNS
they clearly defined "work" as labor performed outside the home
for wages. By describing themselves as the sole support of the
family, men undervalued the services they received in return for
the wages they contributed.
The exaltation of domestic virtue, growing class inequalities,
patriarchal interests-all of these factors contributed to new char-
acterizations of household labor. But the most specific evidence of
literal devaluation lies in the history of Anglo-American political
economy. In both theory and practice, this emerging science
showed a distinct tendency to treat women's household work in
moral rather than economic terms. The result was a new statistical
categorization of housewives that gradually found expression in the
censuses of population.
England and Wales
England was home to the classics of political economy, and her
censuses provided a model for the data-gathering practices of her
colonies and, later, her Commonwealth. Unlike the United States,
where the Constitution mandated a decennial census that helped
determine political representation, the early censuses of Great
Britain were incorporated into the existing vital registry system
and, as such, were heavily influenced by medical concerns such as
the measurement of infant mortality.21 Perhaps as a result, early
census practices reflected physicians' appreciation of the difficul-
ties of rearing children, rather than economists' lack of interest in
such forms of work.
From the very outset, political economy was preoccupied with
the distinction between productive and unproductive labor. In the
eighteenth century, the French Physiocrats suggested that agricul-
ture was the only true source of surplus and described profits
earned in manufacturing as a mere redistribution. But the Scottish
economist Adam Smith offered a spirited defense of manufacturing
and called for a new definition of productive labor, based on the
addition of "net value" to a vendible commodity.22 He argued that
services were unproductive because they did not contribute to the
accumulation of physical wealth. Domestic servants, for example,
merely enhanced their employers' standard of living.
21 J. M. Eyler, Victorian Social Medicine: The Ideas and Methods of William Farr
(Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press, 1979).
2 Mark Blaug, Economic Theory in Retrospect, 4th ed. (Cambridge: Cambridge
University Press, 1985).
469
This content downloaded from 154.59.124.94 on Sun, 28 May 2017 11:03:11 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
Folbre / UNPRODUCTIVE HOUSEWIFE
Smith used the term "productive" primarily to distinguish
activities that he believed contributed to economic growth. Most of
his immediate successors in the field, including David Ricardo,
Thomas Robert Malthus, and John Stuart Mill, followed suit. But
none agreed completely with the terms of Smith's definitions. Mill,
in particular, argued that some services, such as the training of
workers, contributed to economic growth and should be deemed
productive.23 Partly because the issue was never resolved, the
classical dichotomy between productive and unproductive labor
was gradually replaced by a new distinction between market and
nonmarket labor.
By the end of the nineteenth century, most economists had come
to agree that all paid services should be considered productive, and
many advocated that the term "unproductive" be dropped from the
language of their discipline.24 Yet, almost to a man, they also agreed
that nonmarket services lay outside the realm of economics and
therefore did not contribute to economic growth. While paid
domestic servants were considered part of the labor force, unpaid
domestic workers were not. Nonmarket production-a wife's work
in the home, for instance-was implicitly defined as unproductive.
This sharp distinction between the household and the market
was not reflected in the early censuses of Great Britain. Following
an unsuccessful attempt in 1801 to collect information on the
occupations of individuals, the censuses of 1811, 1821, and 1831
inquired after the occupations of families as productive units. As
Catherine Hakim points out, "The idea of an individual male
wage-earner supporting his family was unfamiliar in the first half of
the nineteenth century. It was assumed that all members of the
household contributed to the family enterprise in agriculture, trade,
or handicraft (unless they had independent means)."25 In 1831
occupations of males age twenty or older were enumerated sepa-
rately, as were those of female servants of all ages. In 1851, for the
first time, general female occupations were enumerated.26 The list
of categories to which they could be assigned included nonmarket
household work as well as paid occupations such as teacher or
dressmaker.
3 William J. Barber, A History of Economic Thought (New York: Penguin, 1979),
97.
24 Joseph Schumpeter, History of Economic Analysis (New York: Oxford Univer-
sity Press, 1954), 628; The New Palgrave: A Dictionary of Economics, ed. John
Eatwell, Murray Milgate, and Peter Newman (London: Macmillan, 1987), 1008.
25 Catherine Hakim, "Census Reports as Documentary Evidence: The Census
Commentaries, 1801-1951," Sociological Review 28, no. 3 (August 1980): 551-80,
esp. 554.
26 Census of Great Britain, 1851, vol. 1, Population, British Parliamentary Papers
(Dublin: Irish University Press, 1970), Ixix.
470
This content downloaded from 154.59.124.94 on Sun, 28 May 2017 11:03:11 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
Spring 1991 / SIGNS
Under the influence of the physician William Farr, the 1851
census placed "wives, mothers and mistresses" in a category by
themselves, the "Fifth Class" among the occupations. Women with
occupations outside the home were grouped accordingly in differ-
ent classes. Still another class (the "Seventeenth," to be precise)
was reserved for "dependents," or those supported by the commu-
nity: "children, the sick and infirm, gypsies and vagrants, and
certain ladies and gentlemen of independent means."27 The official
discussion of the tabulations conveyed a strong appreciation of
domestic work: "The most important production of a country is its
population."2 The text went on to deplore women's employment
outside the home.
In their critical analyses of the early English censuses, Desley
Deacon and Edward Higgs both emphasize the influence of Farr's
medical orientation.29 But Farr was by no means immune to the
predominant opinions of political economists. The tenor of the
discussion of women's work in the census volumes he supervised
changed over time. In the 1861 Census of England and Wales,
wives and widows "not otherwise described" were included in
class 2, the "Domestic Class," along with scholars, paid domestic
workers, entertainers, and people who performed personal ser-
vices, such as barbers. But the census discussion seemed somewhat
apologetic: "These women are sometimes returned as of no occu-
pation. But the occupation of wife and mother and housewife is the
most important in the country, as will be immediately apparent if it
be assumed for a moment to be suppressed."30
The 1871 census used similar categories, but more openly
confronted its nomenclatural dilemma. The notes comment that the
occupation of wife and mother is "a noble and essential" one, but
they also call attention to the increase in women's factory employ-
ment, a rapid increase in "the proportion of women engaged
specifically in productive work."31 The language suggests that
unpaid domestic labor, however noble, was not truly productive.
Still, the suggestion remained just that; wives and mothers
could have been but were not included in the new category termed
"Indefinite and Non-productive," which included people without
27 Celia Davies, "Making Sense of the Census in Britain and the U.S.A.: The
Changing Occupational Classification and the Position of Nurses," Sociological
Review 28, no. 3 (August 1980): 581-609.
28 Census of Great Britain, 1851, lxxxviii.
29 Deacon (n. 3 above); see also Edward Higgs, "Women, Occupations, and Work
in the Nineteenth-Century Censuses," History Workshop 23 (Spring 1987): 59-80.
30 Census of England and Wales, 1861 and 1871, British Parliamentary Papers
(Dublin: Irish University Press, 1970) 33.
31 Ibid., xlii.
471
This content downloaded from 154.59.124.94 on Sun, 28 May 2017 11:03:11 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
Folbre / UNPRODUCTIVE HOUSEWIFE
specified occupations and those whose occupations were described
in general or vague terms. William Farr retired shortly after the
1871 census appeared, and terminology shifted more decisively in
the 1881 census. Wives and other women engaged in domestic
duties were explicitly placed in the "Unoccupied Class," which
apparently replaced the earlier "Indefinite and Non-productive"
category. The discussion noted that many of the "unoccupied"
were women, "of whom by far the greater part were married and
engaged in the management of domestic life, and who can only be
called unoccupied, when that term is used in the limited sense that
it bears in the Census Returns. Many more of these women, though
unmarried, were also engaged in domestic duties, or were assisting
their fathers or other near relatives in the details of business.""32
Having previously apologized for counting wives and mothers
occupied, the registry now apologized for doing just the opposite.
In 1890, a parliamentary committee was convened to consider
improvements to the census. The prominent neoclassical econo-
mist Alfred Marshall, who was called to testify, held up a recent
German census as an example of superior methodology. Marshall
complained that the English occupational categories failed to
explain the distinctions between skilled and unskilled labor.33 He
was also dissatisfied with the large numbers in the "Unoccupied"
column and urged the committee to eliminate it. "In other coun-
tries," he explained, "you see the dependents upon anybody who is
occupied are entered as dependent, and therefore the figures in this
column (unoccupied) are very small."34
Marshall clearly agreed with the German convention of describ-
ing married women as "dependents," a description far more con-
sistent with the tradition of English political economy than previous
census practices. According to the diaries of the prominent socia
reformer Beatrice Webb, who opposed women's suffrage at the time
she met him, Marshall strongly disliked and disapproved of the
prospect of female independence.35 His classic Principles of Eco-
32 Census of England and Wales, 1881, British Parliamentary Papers (Dublin:
Irish University Press, 1970), 63.
33 Report of the Committee Appointed by the Treasury to Inquire into Certain
Questions Connected with the Taking of the Census, British Parliamentary Papers
(c. 6071), LVIII, 13, 68.
34 Ibid., 66.
35 Glitter Around and Darkness Within, vol. 1 (1873-92) of The Diary of Beatrice
Webb, ed. Norman and Jeanne McKenzie (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University
Press, 1982), 273. The entire passage follows: "Conversation with Professor Mar-
shall, he holding that woman was a subordinate being, and that, if she ceased to be
subordinate, there would be no object for a man to marry, that marriage was a
sacrifice of the masculine freedom and would only be tolerated by male creatures so
472
This content downloaded from 154.59.124.94 on Sun, 28 May 2017 11:03:11 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
Spring 1991 / SIGNS
nomics mentioned only in passing the problematic character of the
new definition of productive labor: "There is however some incon-
sistency in omitting the heavy domestic work which is done by
women and other members of the household, where no servants are
kept."36
At least one of Marshall's lesser-known contemporaries devoted
slightly more attention to the economic significance of women's
household work: "What this income really amounts to may be
guessed if we imagine what we should have to pay to servants for
doing work now done by wives, sisters, and daughters, and how
entirely impossible it would be to get similar work done for
money," wrote economist William Smart. "If such women went to
the factory or into professional life, we should have to withdraw
probably a much greater number from the factory or professions to
take their place, and should lose something with it all."37 Unfortu-
nately, by the time Smart registered these concerns, a new census
terminology had limited the prospects for empirically assessing
them.
In 1891 the Census of England and Wales restricted the "Do-
mestic Class" to those employed in paid domestic service. The
"Unoccupied Class" simply disappeared from the categories, as
Marshall had recommended. Polite mention was still made of wives
and mothers: "The most important, however, of all female occupa-
tions ... is altogether omitted from the reckoning, namely the
rearing of children and the management of domestic life." If these
were included, the notes continue, the proportion of occupied
women would approach that of men.38
Australia, a major Commonwealth country, shifted its terminol-
ogy in a similar way in 1890. Advocates of a clear emphasis on men
as "breadwinners" and women as "dependents" won a decisive
victory when, in the absence of a clear statement to the contrary,
long as it meant the devotion, body and mind, of the female and no longer. Hence the
woman must develop in no way unpleasant to the man: that strength, courage,
independence were not attractive in women, that rivalry in men's pursuits was
positively unpleasant. Therefore masculine strength and masculine ability in
women must be firmly trampled on and 'boycotted' by men. Contrast was the
essence of the matrimonial relation: feminine weakness contrasted with masculine
strength, masculine egotism with feminine self-devotion. Naturally enough I main-
tained the opposite argument; viz. that there was an ideal of character in which
strength, courage, sympathy, self-devotion, persistent purpose were united to a clear
and far-seeing intellect: that this ideal was common to the man and the woman."
3 Marshall (n. 13 above), 80.
37 William Smart, The Distribution of Income (New York: Macmillan, 1899), 69.
38 Census of England and Wales, 1891, British Parliamentary Papers (Dublin:
Irish University Press), 58.
473
This content downloaded from 154.59.124.94 on Sun, 28 May 2017 11:03:11 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
Folbre / UNPRODUCTIVE HOUSEWIFE
women's work was classified as domestic and they were labeled "de-
pendents." The chief director of the New South Wales census "argued
that both women's contributions to family economies and their com-
petition for jobs lowered the wages of men and the community's stan-
dard of living."39 National statistics showing a low rate of female labor-
force participation would, he believed, enhance Australia's image as a
prosperous colony worthy of English investment.
The United States
The grand tradition of English political economy shaped the U
federal censuses from the outset. The lack of connection with a vi
statistics registry may have deflected attention from child rearin
and other domestic activities. The standard occupational categor
consistently ignored women's household labor, and protests b
feminists, however articulate, had no apparent impact.
In the United States, political economists never fully endors
Smith's distinction between productive and unproductive labor
Yet they were remarkably unanimous in their low opinion
women's capacity for important work. The absence of discussi
before the 1880s was perhaps more significant than the few remar
that were made. Noteworthy, however, was the well-known politi-
cal economist Amasa Walker's insistence that women's wages
should be low because "the prevailing ideas of the community
restrict them to easily dispensible occupations."41 The eminent
southerner Thomas Dew held that women's qualities of mind fitted
them for subservient roles.42
Such ideas had little discernible influence on the early censuses
of population, which, as in England and Wales, focused on families
rather than individuals. In 1820, the first year that economic
activities became a topic of concern, the federal census tallied the
number of families engaged in agriculture, commerce, and manu-
facturing.43 The 1830 census included no reference to occupations,
but the 1840 census basically followed the 1820 format.
39 Deacon (n. 3 above), 35.
40 Paul K. Conkin, Prophets of Prosperity: America's First Political Economists
(Bloomington: Indiana University Press, 1980), 147.
41 Joseph Dorfman, The Economic Mind in American Civilization (New York:
Kelley, 1969), 750.
42 Ibid., 908.
43 Still, even at this early date "household manufactures" were explicitly distin-
guished from others as "only incidental, and not the profession properly marking the
class of society to which such individual belongs." These words, attributed to John
Quincy Adams, suggests that the census was more interested in "properly marking"
class (broadly construed to include the class of housewives) rather than counting the
474
This content downloaded from 154.59.124.94 on Sun, 28 May 2017 11:03:11 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
Spring 1991 / SIGNS
As industrial employment grew, so did interest in individual
occupations. In 1850 the census inquired after the "profession,
occupation, or trade of each male person over 15 years of age."44 In
1860 and thereafter, this inquiry was extended to women. Unlike
the Census of England and Wales, the U.S. Census did not officially
recognize the occupation of housewife.
The influence of political economic theory became particularly
apparent in 1870, when Francis Amasa Walker, son of Amasa
Walker, took charge of the census. Of all the nineteenth-century
stewards of official statistics, Walker was by far the most academi-
cally prestigious. President of the Massachusetts Institute of Tech-
nology, he also presided over the American Economics Association
from 1885 to 1892.45
Under his aegis, the census explicitly stipulated a wage/salary
criterion for women's occupations: "The term 'housekeeper' will
be reserved for such persons as receive distinct wages or salary for
the service. Women keeping house for their own families or for
themselves, without any other gainful occupation, will be entered
as 'keeping house.' "46 This wording implies that keeping house
was a gainful occupation, despite its lack of inclusion in the
aggregate tabulations.
Francis Walker supported women's right to vote and argued that
they should have greater access to jobs outside the home-to a
degree. Like his father, who described women as "incapable of self
support," Walker had a low opinion of women's productive capac-
ities.47 His views on the family were distinctly Malthusian. Men
undertook the support of women in "obedience to a natural instinct
second only, in the demand it makes on men, to the craving for
food."48 Having distinguished himself in the Civil War, Walker was
often addressed as "General." His description of women's assigned
role in primitive economies reads like a list of military directives:
"She will spin and weave... she will bring water.... She will
true extent of manufacturing. See Carroll Wright, The History and Growth of the
U.S. Census (Washington, D.C.: Government Printing Office, 1900), 135.
44 Ibid., 147.
45 James Phinney Munroe, A Life of Francis Amasa Walker (New York: Henry
Holt, 1923), 328; Robert Solow, "What Do We Know That Francis Amasa Walker
Didn't?" History of Political Economy 19, no. 2 (Summer 1987): 183-90.
6 Wright, The History and Growth of the U.S. Census, 159.
47 Amasa Walker, The Science of Wealth, A Manual of Political Economy,
Embracing the Laws of Trade, Currency, and Finance (1874; reprint, Boston: Little,
Brown, 1969).
48 Francis Walker, Political Economy (1883; reprint, New York: Henry Holt,
1911), 297.
475
This content downloaded from 154.59.124.94 on Sun, 28 May 2017 11:03:11 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
Folbre / UNPRODUCTIVE HOUSEWIFE
keep the hut or tent in a certain order and decency." He went on t
make it absolutely clear that women in such economies were no
productive workers: "We may assume that speaking broadly, sh
does not produce as much as she consumes."49
Walker's conviction that women's household work was unpro
ductive spilled over into the census's measurement of women's
participation in the market economy. By Walker's own accoun
women with occupations outside the home were underenumerate
He attributed this largely to social custom and enumerator bias.
the 1870 U.S. Census, Walker wrote, "it is taken for granted th
every man has an occupation, and the examination of tens o
thousands of pages of schedules returned in the present census has
satisfied the superintendent that only in rare cases . . . have assi
tant marshals failed to ask and obtain the occupation of men, or boy
old enough to work with effect. It is precisely the other way with
women and young children. The assumption is, as the fact gener
ally is, that they are not engaged in remunerative employment
Those who are so engaged constitute the exception, and it follow
from a plain principle of human nature, that assistant marshals wi
not infrequently forget or neglect to ask the question."50 Wom
who took in boarders and lodgers, helped with the family farm
business, or contracted industrial homework from factories we
not counted among the gainfully occupied, even though they we
earning money.51
The depreciation of women's domestic labor had long been a
theme of feminist protest. Early socialist feminists such as William
Thompson and Frances Wright raised the issue in England durin
the 1830s, and so-called material feminists in the United State
called for more efficient organization of domestic labor, includi
collective facilities for meals that could take full advantage of new
cooking technologies.52 In the 1860s, as the National Women's
Suffrage Association explored the possibility of alliances with
progressive trade unions, many of its members emphasized th
49 Ibid.
50 Ibid., 375.
51 For a more detailed discussion of the underenumeration of women's market
work, see Christine Bose, "Devaluing Women's Work: The Undercount of Women's
Employment in 1900," in Hidden Aspects of Women's Work, ed. Christine Bose,
Roslyn Feldberg, and Natalie Sokoloff (New York: Praeger, 1987); and Nancy Folbre
and Marjorie Abel, "Women's Work and Women's Households: Gender Bias in the
U.S. Census," Social Research 56, no. 3 (Autumn 1989): 545-70.
52 Barbara Taylor, Eve and the New Jerusalem: Socialism and Feminism in the
Nineteenth Century (New York: Pantheon, 1983); Dolores Hayden, The Grand
Domestic Revolution: A History of Feminist Designs for American Homes, Neigh-
borhoods, and Cities (Cambridge, Mass.: MIT Press, 1981).
476
This content downloaded from 154.59.124.94 on Sun, 28 May 2017 11:03:11 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
Spring 1991 / SIGNS
drudgery of household work and the exploitation of women who
performed it. Elizabeth Cady Stanton declared that women's do-
mestic work differed from that of men only because it was "unpaid,
unsocialized, and unrelenting."53 Elizabeth Blackwell wrote, "The
theory that a wife who .. . bears her fair share of the joint burdens,
is yet 'supported' by her husband has been the bane of all society."54
Some progressive trade unionists within the Knights of Labor fully
agreed.55
Explicit feminist criticism of the census originated with the
Association for the Advancement of Women, a group founded in
1873 that included many of the most highly educated women of the
day. The Commonwealth of Massachusetts was particularly well
represented by Julia Ward Howe, a prominent feminist activist;
Melusina Fay Pierce, famous for her advocacy of the collectiviza-
tion of housework; and Maria Mitchell, a Harvard astronomer.
Sometimes affectionately dubbed the "Ladies' Social Science As-
sociation," the group held annual conferences throughout the 1890s
and helped design the Women's Exhibit for the Centenniai Expo-
sition of 1876.56
The AAW's concerns were hardly limited to the "twelve millions
of American women being overlooked as laborers or producers" (see
Appendix). Consonant with their own professional interests, the
members pointed out that the census could improve the quality of
its statistics on women and children by hiring intelligent women as
enumerators. Summaries of the conference proceedings included no
mention of a response until a short retrospective essay was pub-
lished in 1893. Apparently, Walker had invoked the cult of domes-
ticity in his own defense. Ladies themselves, he argued, were re-
luctant to acknowledge that they worked for a living.57
In 1900, the U.S. Census adopted a new use for the term
"breadwinner," cautioning that "it must be understood in a sense
somewhat different from its usual one ... it does not include a
person who has retired from practice or business or a wife or
daughter living at home and assisting only in the household duties
53 The Revolution, ed. Susan B. Anthony and Elizabeth Cady Stanton (December
24, 1868), 393.
4 Cited in William Leach, True Love and Perfect Union (New York: Basic, 1980)
193.
55 Susan Levine, Labor's True Woman: Carpet Weavers, Industrialization and
Labor Reform in the Gilded Age (Philadelphia: Temple University Press, 1984).
56 Leach, 292-322.
57 American Association for the Advancement of Women, Historical Account of
the Association for the Advancement of Women, 1873-1893, Twenty-first Women'
Congress, World's Columbian Exposition, Chicago (Dedham, Mass.: Transcrip
Steam Job Print, 1893), 9.
477
This content downloaded from 154.59.124.94 on Sun, 28 May 2017 11:03:11 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
Folbre / UNPRODUCTIVE HOUSEWIFE
without pay."58 Wives and daughters without a paying job were
officially designated "dependents." State censuses became increas-
ingly common in the late nineteenth century, and most of them
conformed to federal format and terminology.59 The Commonwealth
of Massachusetts, however, proved an important exception.
The Massachusetts anomaly
The 1875 State Census of Massachusetts, probably the most ambi-
tious of its day, collected and compiled an unusual variety of social
statistics. Its complexity may have obscured its English-style cate-
gorization of women's domestic work, which received little or no
attention. Its terminological anomalies represent an interesting
detour from federal census practices that only gradually converged
with the main road.
In 1875, housewives and unmarried women who performed
housework without remuneration were included in the larger
category of "Domestic and Personal Office," along with subcatego-
ries for paid employment such as housekeepers, servants, nurses,
and washerwomen. The introduction to the first volume makes it
clear that a housewife's work was considered productive: "The
terms non-productive and unemployed are applied to all who take
no part in the work of life."60 Indeed, a separate occupational
category was reserved for the "non-productive and propertied."
Traces of the old-fashioned Smithian emphasis on production of
material goods remained. The introductory notes observe that only
occupations in agriculture, fisheries, manufacturing, and mechani-
cal industries, as well as apprentices and laborers, actually pro-
duced things. All services, though they may have been performed
for pay, were seen as distinct from agriculture and manufacturing-
and were, by implication, somewhat suspect.
Married women were not automatically assumed to be housewives.
Some were described as "having nothing to do but superintend the
households," and there were those who did even less than that. In the
census's own words, "there are 4,786 wives of heads simply ornamen-
tal."6' These amounted to less than 2 percent of all wives.
Twelfth Census of the United States, 1900 (n. 5 above), 225.
59 This generalization is based on scrutiny of nineteenth-century censuses from
states in which more than eight censuses were taken: New York, Michigan, and
Iowa, as well as the western states of Texas and Colorado. The majority of states did
not conduct systematic censuses during the nineteenth century, and interest in
occupational categories was limited to the most industrialized states.
60 The Census of Massachusetts: 1875 (Boston: Albert J. Wright, 1876), xlix.
61 Ibid., 1.
478
This content downloaded from 154.59.124.94 on Sun, 28 May 2017 11:03:11 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
Spring 1991 / SIGNS
The 1885 State Census of Massachusetts dropped the "non-
productive and propertied" category and introduced a variety of
new categories in its place, including "retired"-"those possessed
of a competency, inherited or acquired, or for some reasons, do not
need to be actively engaged in order to obtain a subsistence, as
distinguished from those persons classified as 'dependents,' mostly
in private families, who are more or less dependent upon relatives
or friends for their support."62 Similarly, the term "non-productive"
was reserved for "those afflicted persons, homeless children, pau-
pers, prisoners, and convicts, who by reason of their disabilities,
etc., have no productive occupations." This census used the terms
"dependent" and "non-productive" quite restrictively. They were
not used to label housewives.
But the text that accompanied the tabulations in 1885 reflected
a major concession to the emerging conventional wisdom. House-
wives and women who performed unpaid housework, along with
scholars and students, were subtracted from the total to arrive at
"remunerative occupations." The definition of the word "house-
wife" itself shifted away from one based on actual work performed
to more general, social terms: "By housewives are meant the female
heads of household, that is, the wife or some person in the family
who has general charge of the domestic affairs."63 "Housework,"
used to describe the work of unmarried people who performed
unpaid domestic labor, retained a specific meaning at least some-
what independent of gender. Of 89,062 people so engaged,
seventy-seven were males.
The apparent contradictions persist in the 1895 Massachusetts
census. Housewives and housework are tabulated in "Domestic
Service," rather than in the "not gainful," "not productive," or
"dependent" categories. But in 1905, the Massachusetts census
surrendered its eccentricities and placed housewives and house-
work in the "not gainful" class, along with scholars, students,
retirees, those unemployed for twelve months, and dependents.
The "Domestic and Personal Service" category was limited to
those who received a wage or salary for their work.
This terminological shift was discussed in the twentieth annual
report of the Massachusetts Bureau of Statistics of Labor (1889),
which summarized the findings of the 1885 census regarding
women in industry. The lengthy explanation of why women were
excluded from the "remunerative occupations" had an apologetic
62 The Census of Massachusetts: 1885, prepared under the direction of Carroll D.
Wright, vol. 1, Population and Social Statistics (Boston: Wright & Potter, 1888), xxi.
63 Ibid., xxv.
479
This content downloaded from 154.59.124.94 on Sun, 28 May 2017 11:03:11 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
Folbre / UNPRODUCTIVE HOUSEWIFE
tone reminiscent of that found in the Census of England and Wales
after 1880. But the discussion, far more assertive in its criticism of
the conventional wisdom, anticipated William Smart's questions
regarding the implicit value of unpaid domestic labor-in short
what it could cost, were it paid for:
To be sure, [housewives] receive no stated salary or wage,
but their work is surely worth what it would cost to have it
done, supposing that the housewife, as such, did no work at
all. There were 372,612 housewives in Massachusetts in
1885, and only 300,999 women engaged in all other branches
of industry. If a housewife were not expected nor required to
work, then for the labor of 372,612 women paid service
would have to be substituted. Such a demand for labor could
not be supplied by the inhabitants of the State itself. Conse-
quently, as the labor of the housewives was absolutely
necessary to allow society to exist in its present form, the
housewife is certainly "in industry." As has been stated, she
is excluded from the previous tables in this Part for conven-
tional and arbitrary reasons alone. The housewife is as much
a member of the army of workers as the clerk or cotton
weaver, and too often supplements the toil of the day, "in
industry" with household duties performed at home, but
outside of the "in industry" classification.4
The author of this prescient explanation remains a mystery,
although Horace Wadlin, director of the Boston Public Library, was
in command of the Massachusetts Bureau of Labor at the time.
Responsibility for the more generous English-style terminology of
the 1875 and 1885 censuses lies almost certainly with then-director
Carroll Wright, who had a unique, if undeveloped, theoretical
perspective on women's household work. The 1875 Massachusetts
census represented his official debut as one of the most influential
statisticians of the late nineteenth century. Wright, who also served
as a special agent for the 1880 U.S. Census, was appointed U.S.
Commissioner of Labor in 1885 and served until 1905. During his
tenure, he presided over the 1890 U.S. Census and many important
census-sponsored studies and reports.
James Leiby's classic study of Wright's lifework describes him
as an autodidact lacking in intellectual stature, who relied heavily
64 Massachusetts Bureau of Labor Statistics, Twentieth Annual Report of the
Bureau of the Statistics of Labor (Boston: Wright & Potter, December 1889), 579.
480
This content downloaded from 154.59.124.94 on Sun, 28 May 2017 11:03:11 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
Spring 1991 / SIGNS
on the advice of Francis Walker.5 Yet the data that Wright collected
may have had a far greater impact on subsequent economic research
than Walker's theoretical or empirical contributions. Wright had an
uncanny instinct for the systematic exploration of politically impor-
tant issues. His classic study, The Working Girls of Boston, was one
of the first efforts to examine the implications of factory employ-
ment. In it, Wright argued that the length of the working day for
women should be limited to ten hours in part because, according to
his survey, they did much of their own domestic labor and had little
time for rest.6
Wright eventually became far more sympathetic to feminism
than most of his male counterparts, as evidenced by his article
"Why Women Earn Less Than Men," which acknowledged the
discrimination women faced.67 His Massachusetts background
meant that he almost inevitably came into contact with some of the
more prominent members of the Association for the Advancement
of Women. But Wright's adherence to the concept of the productive
housewife, though admirable, was neither strong nor persistent.
His voluminous writings were largely preoccupied with relations
between labor and capital. Even his published address to the
American Social Science Association on "Problems of the Census"
in 1887 omitted any consideration of household labor.
The implications of a new terminology
The censuses of England, the United States, and Massachusetts
reveal the emergence of a new terminology that clearly labeled
housework unproductive. What do these examples tell us about the
coevolution of political economy and its more pragmatic language
of measurement? The concept of the unproductive housewife was
a by-product of a new definition of productive labor that valorized
participation in the market and devalorized the nonmarket work
central to many women's lives. The terminological shift formalized
the assumptions of androcentric political economy.
This shift was not unique to one country. Given Alfred Marshall's
recommendation that England import the German practice of cat-
65 James Leiby, Carroll Wright and Labor Reform: The Origin of Labor Statistics
(Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1960).
66 Carroll Wright, "The Working Girls of Boston," Fifteenth Annual Report of the
Bureau of the Statistics of Labor (Boston: Wright & Potter, July 1884), 129.
67 Carroll Wright, "Why Women Earn Less Than Men," Forum (July 1892),
629-39.
481
This content downloaded from 154.59.124.94 on Sun, 28 May 2017 11:03:11 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
Folbre / UNPRODUCTIVE HOUSEWIFE
egorizing housewives as dependents, it cannot be attributed simply
to Victorian ideology writ large. Nor did the shift go unnoticed
William Farr and Carroll Wright both resisted it initially. The A
sociation for the Advancement of Women actively protested it.
Why, then, did it not stir more discussion and debate? Part of the
answer lies in the ease with which upper-class men could arrive a
a comfortable consensus concerning women's capacities and con
tributions. The evolution of census terminology resonates with the
story that social historians have told about the functional aspects of
the "breadwinner/dependent ideal."" Indeed, it suggests that his
torians may have underestimated the importance of new cultur
conceptions of work by failing to recognize the ways that gende
bias influenced "objective" measurements of women's productive
work.
Political pressures influenced the way in which late nineteenth-
century social statistics were collected in the United States. Th
Massachusetts Bureau of Labor was created largely in response t
agitation by a labor group, the Knights of Saint Crispin. The Knight
of Labor successfully demanded a Federal Bureau of Labor.6 Th
Divorce Reform League prompted the Federal Bureau's study o
marriage and divorce statistics in the United States, which Carro
Wright conducted in 1889. When Wright first assumed his respon-
sibilities at the new Federal Bureau of Labor, his interest in
developing a major study of African-American workers was discour-
aged because of concern that southern Congressmen would be
offended.70 If African-Americans or women had had more political
power, even an effective right to vote, U.S. census categories might
have evolved differently.
A melange of theoretical, political, and practical concerns influ-
enced census designers. Yet their categories, in turn, exerted
tremendous influence on both everyday politics and economic
theory. By 1900, the notion that married women without paying
jobs outside the home were "dependents" had acquired the status
of a scientific fact. Women's economic dependence commonly was
used to explain their lower wages-they did not need a living wage.
Indeed, men demanded a higher wage so that they might support
their dependent wives.71
" See Hartmann (n. 18 above); Seccombe (n. 17 above); and Rose (n. 18 above).
69 Carroll Wright, "The Working of the Department of Labor," in Monographs on
Social Economics, ed. Chas. H. Verrill (U.S. Department of Labor Exhibit, Pan
American Exhibition, 1901), 1.
70 Leiby, 105.
1 Carroll Wright, The Industrial Evolution of the United States (New York:
Charles Scribner's, 1901), 212; Sidney Webb (n. 18 above), 78; Barbara Meyer
482
This content downloaded from 154.59.124.94 on Sun, 28 May 2017 11:03:11 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
Spring 1991 / SIGNS
The result was a certain symmetry between private, public, and
academic assumptions. The new terminology made it difficult to
explain how a married man benefited from his wife's household
labor or, similarly, how the larger economy benefited from nonmar-
ket work. Those few scholars who remained interested in house-
hold production stepped outside the traditions of political economy
to found the new discipline of home economics. In that sphere, the
productive housewife lived on, in theory as well as in practice.
Department of Economics
University of Massachusetts-Amherst
Appendix
Memorial of Mary F. Eastman, Henrietta L. T. Woolcott, and others,
officers of the Association for the Advancement of Women, praying that the
tenth census may contain a just enumeration of women as laborers and
producers.
To the Senate and House of Representatives of the United States in
Congress assembled:
Whereas the acknowledged errors, discrepancies, and incompleteness of
the Ninth Census render it an unsatisfactory and unreliable record of the
population, wealth, industry, and physical, mental and moral conditions of
the American people; and
Whereas the home and woman as a home-keeper have no place in the
report, only the occupations called "gainful" being noted, and more than
twelve millions of American women being overlooked as laborers or
producers or left out, in common with those pursuing disreputable em-
ployments, and not even incidentally named as in any wise affecting the
causes or increase or decrease of population or wealth; and
Whereas gross errors in enumerating the births, ages, diseases, and
deaths of children are the inevitable result of the natural barriers in the
way of men as collectors of social and vital statistics, who frequently obtain
information, in the language of the report, from "fathers, nurses, servants,
and unsympathetic fellow-boarders"; and
Whereas there is obvious justice and propriety in the employment of
intelligent women to collect vital statistics concerning women and chil-
dren:
Therefore we pray your honorable body, in enacting a law providing
for the taking of the Tenth Census, to make provision for the more careful
Wertheimer, We Were There: The Story of Working Women in America (New York:
Pantheon, 1977), 207.
483
This content downloaded from 154.59.124.94 on Sun, 28 May 2017 11:03:11 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
Folbre / UNPRODUCTIVE HOUSEWIFE
and just enumeration of women as laborers and producers; for a record of
the wages of men and women in all occupations; for a record of causes of
pauperism, vagrancy, vice and crime, insanity, idiocy, blindness, deformity
and disease; for the enumeration of all men and women engaged in
disreputable occupations, for full statistics concerning all reformato
institutions; and
We further pray that you will enact such laws or amendments as may b
requisite to secure the employment of a fair ratio of suitable women
collectors of the centennial census.
Mary T. Eastman, Massachusetts, Secretary Association for Advance-
ment of Women, et al.
484
This content downloaded from 154.59.124.94 on Sun, 28 May 2017 11:03:11 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms

More Related Content

What's hot

Feminist Economics, Finance and the Commons
Feminist Economics, Finance and the CommonsFeminist Economics, Finance and the Commons
Feminist Economics, Finance and the CommonsConor McCabe
 
Austin Tx Demographics - Census 2010
Austin Tx Demographics - Census 2010Austin Tx Demographics - Census 2010
Austin Tx Demographics - Census 2010Kristen Carney
 
Womens Movements Econ Power Khan Veneklasen 2012
Womens Movements Econ Power Khan Veneklasen 2012Womens Movements Econ Power Khan Veneklasen 2012
Womens Movements Econ Power Khan Veneklasen 2012Alia Khan
 
02 cernic urban-rural%20-life%20setting%20as%20the%20explanatory%20factor%20of..
02 cernic urban-rural%20-life%20setting%20as%20the%20explanatory%20factor%20of..02 cernic urban-rural%20-life%20setting%20as%20the%20explanatory%20factor%20of..
02 cernic urban-rural%20-life%20setting%20as%20the%20explanatory%20factor%20of..tuyagerel
 
Davies j curve original
Davies j curve originalDavies j curve original
Davies j curve originalEric Strayer
 
Migrations Bibliography
Migrations BibliographyMigrations Bibliography
Migrations Bibliographyrwebb7
 
The_Decline_and_Rise_of_Interstate_Migra
The_Decline_and_Rise_of_Interstate_MigraThe_Decline_and_Rise_of_Interstate_Migra
The_Decline_and_Rise_of_Interstate_Migra*****Dominic A Ienco
 
Women and Social Movements Library - Key Topics
Women and Social Movements Library - Key TopicsWomen and Social Movements Library - Key Topics
Women and Social Movements Library - Key TopicsProQuest
 
Lessons from a rock star economist - ft.com
Lessons from a rock star economist - ft.comLessons from a rock star economist - ft.com
Lessons from a rock star economist - ft.comCarlo Favaretti
 
People and lifestyles in the metropolis
People and lifestyles in the metropolisPeople and lifestyles in the metropolis
People and lifestyles in the metropolisErin Graves
 
Professor Martin McKee: health and human rights in Europe?
Professor Martin McKee: health and human rights in Europe?Professor Martin McKee: health and human rights in Europe?
Professor Martin McKee: health and human rights in Europe?UKFacultyPublicHealth
 
Slavery, education, and inequality. Graziella Bertocchi & Arcangelo Dimico
Slavery, education, and inequality. Graziella Bertocchi & Arcangelo DimicoSlavery, education, and inequality. Graziella Bertocchi & Arcangelo Dimico
Slavery, education, and inequality. Graziella Bertocchi & Arcangelo Dimicoeraser Juan José Calderón
 
CONF_SOCCAP_VERMAAK
CONF_SOCCAP_VERMAAKCONF_SOCCAP_VERMAAK
CONF_SOCCAP_VERMAAKNtila
 
Chap3 m5-malthus theory
Chap3 m5-malthus theoryChap3 m5-malthus theory
Chap3 m5-malthus theoryDao Hoa
 

What's hot (18)

Feminist Economics, Finance and the Commons
Feminist Economics, Finance and the CommonsFeminist Economics, Finance and the Commons
Feminist Economics, Finance and the Commons
 
Austin Tx Demographics - Census 2010
Austin Tx Demographics - Census 2010Austin Tx Demographics - Census 2010
Austin Tx Demographics - Census 2010
 
Lecture13 rightsrevpart1
Lecture13 rightsrevpart1Lecture13 rightsrevpart1
Lecture13 rightsrevpart1
 
Womens Movements Econ Power Khan Veneklasen 2012
Womens Movements Econ Power Khan Veneklasen 2012Womens Movements Econ Power Khan Veneklasen 2012
Womens Movements Econ Power Khan Veneklasen 2012
 
Godoyetal2004
Godoyetal2004Godoyetal2004
Godoyetal2004
 
02 cernic urban-rural%20-life%20setting%20as%20the%20explanatory%20factor%20of..
02 cernic urban-rural%20-life%20setting%20as%20the%20explanatory%20factor%20of..02 cernic urban-rural%20-life%20setting%20as%20the%20explanatory%20factor%20of..
02 cernic urban-rural%20-life%20setting%20as%20the%20explanatory%20factor%20of..
 
Davies j curve original
Davies j curve originalDavies j curve original
Davies j curve original
 
Migrations Bibliography
Migrations BibliographyMigrations Bibliography
Migrations Bibliography
 
aaaaaaaaaaaaaaaaaaaaaaa
aaaaaaaaaaaaaaaaaaaaaaaaaaaaaaaaaaaaaaaaaaaaaa
aaaaaaaaaaaaaaaaaaaaaaa
 
The_Decline_and_Rise_of_Interstate_Migra
The_Decline_and_Rise_of_Interstate_MigraThe_Decline_and_Rise_of_Interstate_Migra
The_Decline_and_Rise_of_Interstate_Migra
 
Women and Social Movements Library - Key Topics
Women and Social Movements Library - Key TopicsWomen and Social Movements Library - Key Topics
Women and Social Movements Library - Key Topics
 
Lessons from a rock star economist - ft.com
Lessons from a rock star economist - ft.comLessons from a rock star economist - ft.com
Lessons from a rock star economist - ft.com
 
People and lifestyles in the metropolis
People and lifestyles in the metropolisPeople and lifestyles in the metropolis
People and lifestyles in the metropolis
 
Professor Martin McKee: health and human rights in Europe?
Professor Martin McKee: health and human rights in Europe?Professor Martin McKee: health and human rights in Europe?
Professor Martin McKee: health and human rights in Europe?
 
Slavery, education, and inequality. Graziella Bertocchi & Arcangelo Dimico
Slavery, education, and inequality. Graziella Bertocchi & Arcangelo DimicoSlavery, education, and inequality. Graziella Bertocchi & Arcangelo Dimico
Slavery, education, and inequality. Graziella Bertocchi & Arcangelo Dimico
 
Malthusian theory explained
Malthusian theory explainedMalthusian theory explained
Malthusian theory explained
 
CONF_SOCCAP_VERMAAK
CONF_SOCCAP_VERMAAKCONF_SOCCAP_VERMAAK
CONF_SOCCAP_VERMAAK
 
Chap3 m5-malthus theory
Chap3 m5-malthus theoryChap3 m5-malthus theory
Chap3 m5-malthus theory
 

Viewers also liked

Inequality in Irish Society: Who Owns Ireland?
Inequality in Irish Society: Who Owns Ireland?Inequality in Irish Society: Who Owns Ireland?
Inequality in Irish Society: Who Owns Ireland?Conor McCabe
 
Irish Commonwealth: Trade Unions and Civil Society in the 21st Century
Irish Commonwealth: Trade Unions and Civil Society in the 21st CenturyIrish Commonwealth: Trade Unions and Civil Society in the 21st Century
Irish Commonwealth: Trade Unions and Civil Society in the 21st CenturyConor McCabe
 
Financial Systems and Social Justice
Financial Systems and Social JusticeFinancial Systems and Social Justice
Financial Systems and Social JusticeConor McCabe
 
Irish Political Economy (YWN), class 4: Credit and Debt
Irish Political Economy (YWN), class 4: Credit and DebtIrish Political Economy (YWN), class 4: Credit and Debt
Irish Political Economy (YWN), class 4: Credit and DebtConor McCabe
 
Financial Markets, Ireland & Instability Feb 2016
Financial Markets, Ireland & Instability Feb 2016Financial Markets, Ireland & Instability Feb 2016
Financial Markets, Ireland & Instability Feb 2016Conor McCabe
 
Week Four:Global Finance, Money & Power - Bonds and shares
Week Four:Global Finance, Money & Power - Bonds and sharesWeek Four:Global Finance, Money & Power - Bonds and shares
Week Four:Global Finance, Money & Power - Bonds and sharesConor McCabe
 
Goodhart two-concepts-money-1998
Goodhart two-concepts-money-1998Goodhart two-concepts-money-1998
Goodhart two-concepts-money-1998Conor McCabe
 
A model for a technological university of the southeast
A model for a technological university of the southeastA model for a technological university of the southeast
A model for a technological university of the southeastConor McCabe
 

Viewers also liked (8)

Inequality in Irish Society: Who Owns Ireland?
Inequality in Irish Society: Who Owns Ireland?Inequality in Irish Society: Who Owns Ireland?
Inequality in Irish Society: Who Owns Ireland?
 
Irish Commonwealth: Trade Unions and Civil Society in the 21st Century
Irish Commonwealth: Trade Unions and Civil Society in the 21st CenturyIrish Commonwealth: Trade Unions and Civil Society in the 21st Century
Irish Commonwealth: Trade Unions and Civil Society in the 21st Century
 
Financial Systems and Social Justice
Financial Systems and Social JusticeFinancial Systems and Social Justice
Financial Systems and Social Justice
 
Irish Political Economy (YWN), class 4: Credit and Debt
Irish Political Economy (YWN), class 4: Credit and DebtIrish Political Economy (YWN), class 4: Credit and Debt
Irish Political Economy (YWN), class 4: Credit and Debt
 
Financial Markets, Ireland & Instability Feb 2016
Financial Markets, Ireland & Instability Feb 2016Financial Markets, Ireland & Instability Feb 2016
Financial Markets, Ireland & Instability Feb 2016
 
Week Four:Global Finance, Money & Power - Bonds and shares
Week Four:Global Finance, Money & Power - Bonds and sharesWeek Four:Global Finance, Money & Power - Bonds and shares
Week Four:Global Finance, Money & Power - Bonds and shares
 
Goodhart two-concepts-money-1998
Goodhart two-concepts-money-1998Goodhart two-concepts-money-1998
Goodhart two-concepts-money-1998
 
A model for a technological university of the southeast
A model for a technological university of the southeastA model for a technological university of the southeast
A model for a technological university of the southeast
 

Similar to Nancy Folbre unproductive-housewife (1991)

Unit VII Discussion Board Need answered tonightImmigrati.docx
Unit VII Discussion Board Need answered tonightImmigrati.docxUnit VII Discussion Board Need answered tonightImmigrati.docx
Unit VII Discussion Board Need answered tonightImmigrati.docxdickonsondorris
 
Chapter ObjeCtivesAfter studying this chapter, you should be.docx
Chapter ObjeCtivesAfter studying this chapter, you should be.docxChapter ObjeCtivesAfter studying this chapter, you should be.docx
Chapter ObjeCtivesAfter studying this chapter, you should be.docxtiffanyd4
 
Cities social issues
Cities social issuesCities social issues
Cities social issuesdwessler
 
Page 1 The British Suffragette Movement The histor.docx
Page  1  The British Suffragette Movement The histor.docxPage  1  The British Suffragette Movement The histor.docx
Page 1 The British Suffragette Movement The histor.docxalfred4lewis58146
 
Feminist Economics - Social Reproduction
Feminist Economics - Social ReproductionFeminist Economics - Social Reproduction
Feminist Economics - Social ReproductionConor McCabe
 
Economic, Social, And Political Problems In The Post-Civil...
Economic, Social, And Political Problems In The Post-Civil...Economic, Social, And Political Problems In The Post-Civil...
Economic, Social, And Political Problems In The Post-Civil...Kristi Anderson
 
Secondary SourcesWhat are Secondary Sources Secondary sou.docx
Secondary SourcesWhat are Secondary Sources Secondary sou.docxSecondary SourcesWhat are Secondary Sources Secondary sou.docx
Secondary SourcesWhat are Secondary Sources Secondary sou.docxbagotjesusa
 
A.p. ch 25 p.p
A.p. ch 25 p.pA.p. ch 25 p.p
A.p. ch 25 p.ptobin15
 
The Development of the Juvenile Court 555CHAPTERAf.docx
The Development of the Juvenile Court 555CHAPTERAf.docxThe Development of the Juvenile Court 555CHAPTERAf.docx
The Development of the Juvenile Court 555CHAPTERAf.docxmehek4
 
WK3 Final Project Framework WorksheetThis worksheet will hel.docx
WK3 Final Project Framework WorksheetThis worksheet will hel.docxWK3 Final Project Framework WorksheetThis worksheet will hel.docx
WK3 Final Project Framework WorksheetThis worksheet will hel.docxambersalomon88660
 
Farming Practices In The Early Twentieth Century
Farming Practices In The Early Twentieth CenturyFarming Practices In The Early Twentieth Century
Farming Practices In The Early Twentieth CenturyTiffany Graham
 
I thank Eric Arnesen, Ava Baron, Jeff Cowie, Leon Fink, Michae.docx
I thank Eric Arnesen, Ava Baron, Jeff Cowie, Leon Fink, Michae.docxI thank Eric Arnesen, Ava Baron, Jeff Cowie, Leon Fink, Michae.docx
I thank Eric Arnesen, Ava Baron, Jeff Cowie, Leon Fink, Michae.docxsheronlewthwaite
 
Tozer, S., Senese, G., & Violas, P. (2013). School and Society - H.docx
Tozer, S., Senese, G., & Violas, P. (2013). School and Society - H.docxTozer, S., Senese, G., & Violas, P. (2013). School and Society - H.docx
Tozer, S., Senese, G., & Violas, P. (2013). School and Society - H.docxedwardmarivel
 
Write response to reading of two article/tutorialoutlet
Write response to reading of two article/tutorialoutletWrite response to reading of two article/tutorialoutlet
Write response to reading of two article/tutorialoutletBridgwood
 
APLOUSD CH 25
APLOUSD CH 25APLOUSD CH 25
APLOUSD CH 25LOAPUSH
 
[Sociology (1).docx
[Sociology (1).docx[Sociology (1).docx
[Sociology (1).docxokawahyu2
 
16I have acquired a lot of knowledge about the histo.docx
16I have acquired a lot of knowledge about the histo.docx16I have acquired a lot of knowledge about the histo.docx
16I have acquired a lot of knowledge about the histo.docxdrennanmicah
 
Family History Essay Examples
Family History Essay ExamplesFamily History Essay Examples
Family History Essay ExamplesElizabeth Lewis
 

Similar to Nancy Folbre unproductive-housewife (1991) (20)

Unit VII Discussion Board Need answered tonightImmigrati.docx
Unit VII Discussion Board Need answered tonightImmigrati.docxUnit VII Discussion Board Need answered tonightImmigrati.docx
Unit VII Discussion Board Need answered tonightImmigrati.docx
 
Chapter ObjeCtivesAfter studying this chapter, you should be.docx
Chapter ObjeCtivesAfter studying this chapter, you should be.docxChapter ObjeCtivesAfter studying this chapter, you should be.docx
Chapter ObjeCtivesAfter studying this chapter, you should be.docx
 
Cities social issues
Cities social issuesCities social issues
Cities social issues
 
Page 1 The British Suffragette Movement The histor.docx
Page  1  The British Suffragette Movement The histor.docxPage  1  The British Suffragette Movement The histor.docx
Page 1 The British Suffragette Movement The histor.docx
 
Feminist Economics - Social Reproduction
Feminist Economics - Social ReproductionFeminist Economics - Social Reproduction
Feminist Economics - Social Reproduction
 
Economic, Social, And Political Problems In The Post-Civil...
Economic, Social, And Political Problems In The Post-Civil...Economic, Social, And Political Problems In The Post-Civil...
Economic, Social, And Political Problems In The Post-Civil...
 
Secondary SourcesWhat are Secondary Sources Secondary sou.docx
Secondary SourcesWhat are Secondary Sources Secondary sou.docxSecondary SourcesWhat are Secondary Sources Secondary sou.docx
Secondary SourcesWhat are Secondary Sources Secondary sou.docx
 
ILIBERAL REFORMS.pdf
ILIBERAL REFORMS.pdfILIBERAL REFORMS.pdf
ILIBERAL REFORMS.pdf
 
A.p. ch 25 p.p
A.p. ch 25 p.pA.p. ch 25 p.p
A.p. ch 25 p.p
 
The Development of the Juvenile Court 555CHAPTERAf.docx
The Development of the Juvenile Court 555CHAPTERAf.docxThe Development of the Juvenile Court 555CHAPTERAf.docx
The Development of the Juvenile Court 555CHAPTERAf.docx
 
WK3 Final Project Framework WorksheetThis worksheet will hel.docx
WK3 Final Project Framework WorksheetThis worksheet will hel.docxWK3 Final Project Framework WorksheetThis worksheet will hel.docx
WK3 Final Project Framework WorksheetThis worksheet will hel.docx
 
Industrialism
IndustrialismIndustrialism
Industrialism
 
Farming Practices In The Early Twentieth Century
Farming Practices In The Early Twentieth CenturyFarming Practices In The Early Twentieth Century
Farming Practices In The Early Twentieth Century
 
I thank Eric Arnesen, Ava Baron, Jeff Cowie, Leon Fink, Michae.docx
I thank Eric Arnesen, Ava Baron, Jeff Cowie, Leon Fink, Michae.docxI thank Eric Arnesen, Ava Baron, Jeff Cowie, Leon Fink, Michae.docx
I thank Eric Arnesen, Ava Baron, Jeff Cowie, Leon Fink, Michae.docx
 
Tozer, S., Senese, G., & Violas, P. (2013). School and Society - H.docx
Tozer, S., Senese, G., & Violas, P. (2013). School and Society - H.docxTozer, S., Senese, G., & Violas, P. (2013). School and Society - H.docx
Tozer, S., Senese, G., & Violas, P. (2013). School and Society - H.docx
 
Write response to reading of two article/tutorialoutlet
Write response to reading of two article/tutorialoutletWrite response to reading of two article/tutorialoutlet
Write response to reading of two article/tutorialoutlet
 
APLOUSD CH 25
APLOUSD CH 25APLOUSD CH 25
APLOUSD CH 25
 
[Sociology (1).docx
[Sociology (1).docx[Sociology (1).docx
[Sociology (1).docx
 
16I have acquired a lot of knowledge about the histo.docx
16I have acquired a lot of knowledge about the histo.docx16I have acquired a lot of knowledge about the histo.docx
16I have acquired a lot of knowledge about the histo.docx
 
Family History Essay Examples
Family History Essay ExamplesFamily History Essay Examples
Family History Essay Examples
 

More from Conor McCabe

Synagogues dublin historical records
Synagogues dublin historical recordsSynagogues dublin historical records
Synagogues dublin historical recordsConor McCabe
 
Trademark May 2021 climate action
Trademark May 2021 climate actionTrademark May 2021 climate action
Trademark May 2021 climate actionConor McCabe
 
Manor House Raheny 13.4.21
Manor House Raheny 13.4.21Manor House Raheny 13.4.21
Manor House Raheny 13.4.21Conor McCabe
 
Equality, Community and the Problem of Irish Finance: Challenges, Blockages, ...
Equality, Community and the Problem of Irish Finance: Challenges, Blockages, ...Equality, Community and the Problem of Irish Finance: Challenges, Blockages, ...
Equality, Community and the Problem of Irish Finance: Challenges, Blockages, ...Conor McCabe
 
Global Finance & Ireland: A Feminist Economics Perspective
Global Finance & Ireland: A Feminist Economics PerspectiveGlobal Finance & Ireland: A Feminist Economics Perspective
Global Finance & Ireland: A Feminist Economics PerspectiveConor McCabe
 
Slí Eíle Talk 23.01.21
Slí Eíle Talk 23.01.21Slí Eíle Talk 23.01.21
Slí Eíle Talk 23.01.21Conor McCabe
 
Apple and Narrative
Apple and NarrativeApple and Narrative
Apple and NarrativeConor McCabe
 
Hope or Austerity? Unite the Union Presentation Mayday 2020
Hope or Austerity? Unite the Union Presentation Mayday 2020Hope or Austerity? Unite the Union Presentation Mayday 2020
Hope or Austerity? Unite the Union Presentation Mayday 2020Conor McCabe
 
Ireland: Politics, Class, and Gender
Ireland: Politics, Class, and GenderIreland: Politics, Class, and Gender
Ireland: Politics, Class, and GenderConor McCabe
 
Trade union left forum oct 19
Trade union left forum oct 19Trade union left forum oct 19
Trade union left forum oct 19Conor McCabe
 
Presentation to Tom Stokes Branch, Unite the Union 12.10.19
Presentation to Tom Stokes Branch, Unite the Union 12.10.19Presentation to Tom Stokes Branch, Unite the Union 12.10.19
Presentation to Tom Stokes Branch, Unite the Union 12.10.19Conor McCabe
 
Lessons from the Financial Crisis - Spare Room, Cork, 29.9.19
Lessons from the Financial Crisis  - Spare Room, Cork,  29.9.19Lessons from the Financial Crisis  - Spare Room, Cork,  29.9.19
Lessons from the Financial Crisis - Spare Room, Cork, 29.9.19Conor McCabe
 
Spare Room Workshop 28 Sept 2019
Spare Room Workshop 28 Sept 2019Spare Room Workshop 28 Sept 2019
Spare Room Workshop 28 Sept 2019Conor McCabe
 
Towards a democratization of money, credit and financial systems
Towards a democratization of money, credit and financial systemsTowards a democratization of money, credit and financial systems
Towards a democratization of money, credit and financial systemsConor McCabe
 
Mary mellor, an eco feminist proposal, nlr 116 117, march june 2019
Mary mellor, an eco feminist proposal, nlr 116 117, march june 2019Mary mellor, an eco feminist proposal, nlr 116 117, march june 2019
Mary mellor, an eco feminist proposal, nlr 116 117, march june 2019Conor McCabe
 
Feminist Economics, Finance, and the Commons
Feminist Economics, Finance, and the CommonsFeminist Economics, Finance, and the Commons
Feminist Economics, Finance, and the CommonsConor McCabe
 
Ireland and Corruption
Ireland and CorruptionIreland and Corruption
Ireland and CorruptionConor McCabe
 
Feminist economics, finance, and the commons
Feminist economics, finance, and the commonsFeminist economics, finance, and the commons
Feminist economics, finance, and the commonsConor McCabe
 
Feminist Economics, the Commons, and Irish Activist Strategies
Feminist Economics, the Commons, and Irish Activist StrategiesFeminist Economics, the Commons, and Irish Activist Strategies
Feminist Economics, the Commons, and Irish Activist StrategiesConor McCabe
 
Finance and Social Justice in Ireland
Finance and Social Justice in IrelandFinance and Social Justice in Ireland
Finance and Social Justice in IrelandConor McCabe
 

More from Conor McCabe (20)

Synagogues dublin historical records
Synagogues dublin historical recordsSynagogues dublin historical records
Synagogues dublin historical records
 
Trademark May 2021 climate action
Trademark May 2021 climate actionTrademark May 2021 climate action
Trademark May 2021 climate action
 
Manor House Raheny 13.4.21
Manor House Raheny 13.4.21Manor House Raheny 13.4.21
Manor House Raheny 13.4.21
 
Equality, Community and the Problem of Irish Finance: Challenges, Blockages, ...
Equality, Community and the Problem of Irish Finance: Challenges, Blockages, ...Equality, Community and the Problem of Irish Finance: Challenges, Blockages, ...
Equality, Community and the Problem of Irish Finance: Challenges, Blockages, ...
 
Global Finance & Ireland: A Feminist Economics Perspective
Global Finance & Ireland: A Feminist Economics PerspectiveGlobal Finance & Ireland: A Feminist Economics Perspective
Global Finance & Ireland: A Feminist Economics Perspective
 
Slí Eíle Talk 23.01.21
Slí Eíle Talk 23.01.21Slí Eíle Talk 23.01.21
Slí Eíle Talk 23.01.21
 
Apple and Narrative
Apple and NarrativeApple and Narrative
Apple and Narrative
 
Hope or Austerity? Unite the Union Presentation Mayday 2020
Hope or Austerity? Unite the Union Presentation Mayday 2020Hope or Austerity? Unite the Union Presentation Mayday 2020
Hope or Austerity? Unite the Union Presentation Mayday 2020
 
Ireland: Politics, Class, and Gender
Ireland: Politics, Class, and GenderIreland: Politics, Class, and Gender
Ireland: Politics, Class, and Gender
 
Trade union left forum oct 19
Trade union left forum oct 19Trade union left forum oct 19
Trade union left forum oct 19
 
Presentation to Tom Stokes Branch, Unite the Union 12.10.19
Presentation to Tom Stokes Branch, Unite the Union 12.10.19Presentation to Tom Stokes Branch, Unite the Union 12.10.19
Presentation to Tom Stokes Branch, Unite the Union 12.10.19
 
Lessons from the Financial Crisis - Spare Room, Cork, 29.9.19
Lessons from the Financial Crisis  - Spare Room, Cork,  29.9.19Lessons from the Financial Crisis  - Spare Room, Cork,  29.9.19
Lessons from the Financial Crisis - Spare Room, Cork, 29.9.19
 
Spare Room Workshop 28 Sept 2019
Spare Room Workshop 28 Sept 2019Spare Room Workshop 28 Sept 2019
Spare Room Workshop 28 Sept 2019
 
Towards a democratization of money, credit and financial systems
Towards a democratization of money, credit and financial systemsTowards a democratization of money, credit and financial systems
Towards a democratization of money, credit and financial systems
 
Mary mellor, an eco feminist proposal, nlr 116 117, march june 2019
Mary mellor, an eco feminist proposal, nlr 116 117, march june 2019Mary mellor, an eco feminist proposal, nlr 116 117, march june 2019
Mary mellor, an eco feminist proposal, nlr 116 117, march june 2019
 
Feminist Economics, Finance, and the Commons
Feminist Economics, Finance, and the CommonsFeminist Economics, Finance, and the Commons
Feminist Economics, Finance, and the Commons
 
Ireland and Corruption
Ireland and CorruptionIreland and Corruption
Ireland and Corruption
 
Feminist economics, finance, and the commons
Feminist economics, finance, and the commonsFeminist economics, finance, and the commons
Feminist economics, finance, and the commons
 
Feminist Economics, the Commons, and Irish Activist Strategies
Feminist Economics, the Commons, and Irish Activist StrategiesFeminist Economics, the Commons, and Irish Activist Strategies
Feminist Economics, the Commons, and Irish Activist Strategies
 
Finance and Social Justice in Ireland
Finance and Social Justice in IrelandFinance and Social Justice in Ireland
Finance and Social Justice in Ireland
 

Recently uploaded

Concept of Vouching. B.Com(Hons) /B.Compdf
Concept of Vouching. B.Com(Hons) /B.CompdfConcept of Vouching. B.Com(Hons) /B.Compdf
Concept of Vouching. B.Com(Hons) /B.CompdfUmakantAnnand
 
Science 7 - LAND and SEA BREEZE and its Characteristics
Science 7 - LAND and SEA BREEZE and its CharacteristicsScience 7 - LAND and SEA BREEZE and its Characteristics
Science 7 - LAND and SEA BREEZE and its CharacteristicsKarinaGenton
 
Mastering the Unannounced Regulatory Inspection
Mastering the Unannounced Regulatory InspectionMastering the Unannounced Regulatory Inspection
Mastering the Unannounced Regulatory InspectionSafetyChain Software
 
Crayon Activity Handout For the Crayon A
Crayon Activity Handout For the Crayon ACrayon Activity Handout For the Crayon A
Crayon Activity Handout For the Crayon AUnboundStockton
 
POINT- BIOCHEMISTRY SEM 2 ENZYMES UNIT 5.pptx
POINT- BIOCHEMISTRY SEM 2 ENZYMES UNIT 5.pptxPOINT- BIOCHEMISTRY SEM 2 ENZYMES UNIT 5.pptx
POINT- BIOCHEMISTRY SEM 2 ENZYMES UNIT 5.pptxSayali Powar
 
A Critique of the Proposed National Education Policy Reform
A Critique of the Proposed National Education Policy ReformA Critique of the Proposed National Education Policy Reform
A Critique of the Proposed National Education Policy ReformChameera Dedduwage
 
Sanyam Choudhary Chemistry practical.pdf
Sanyam Choudhary Chemistry practical.pdfSanyam Choudhary Chemistry practical.pdf
Sanyam Choudhary Chemistry practical.pdfsanyamsingh5019
 
Introduction to AI in Higher Education_draft.pptx
Introduction to AI in Higher Education_draft.pptxIntroduction to AI in Higher Education_draft.pptx
Introduction to AI in Higher Education_draft.pptxpboyjonauth
 
Alper Gobel In Media Res Media Component
Alper Gobel In Media Res Media ComponentAlper Gobel In Media Res Media Component
Alper Gobel In Media Res Media ComponentInMediaRes1
 
Hybridoma Technology ( Production , Purification , and Application )
Hybridoma Technology  ( Production , Purification , and Application  ) Hybridoma Technology  ( Production , Purification , and Application  )
Hybridoma Technology ( Production , Purification , and Application ) Sakshi Ghasle
 
How to Make a Pirate ship Primary Education.pptx
How to Make a Pirate ship Primary Education.pptxHow to Make a Pirate ship Primary Education.pptx
How to Make a Pirate ship Primary Education.pptxmanuelaromero2013
 
Introduction to ArtificiaI Intelligence in Higher Education
Introduction to ArtificiaI Intelligence in Higher EducationIntroduction to ArtificiaI Intelligence in Higher Education
Introduction to ArtificiaI Intelligence in Higher Educationpboyjonauth
 
Call Girls in Dwarka Mor Delhi Contact Us 9654467111
Call Girls in Dwarka Mor Delhi Contact Us 9654467111Call Girls in Dwarka Mor Delhi Contact Us 9654467111
Call Girls in Dwarka Mor Delhi Contact Us 9654467111Sapana Sha
 
Paris 2024 Olympic Geographies - an activity
Paris 2024 Olympic Geographies - an activityParis 2024 Olympic Geographies - an activity
Paris 2024 Olympic Geographies - an activityGeoBlogs
 
Industrial Policy - 1948, 1956, 1973, 1977, 1980, 1991
Industrial Policy - 1948, 1956, 1973, 1977, 1980, 1991Industrial Policy - 1948, 1956, 1973, 1977, 1980, 1991
Industrial Policy - 1948, 1956, 1973, 1977, 1980, 1991RKavithamani
 
Presentation by Andreas Schleicher Tackling the School Absenteeism Crisis 30 ...
Presentation by Andreas Schleicher Tackling the School Absenteeism Crisis 30 ...Presentation by Andreas Schleicher Tackling the School Absenteeism Crisis 30 ...
Presentation by Andreas Schleicher Tackling the School Absenteeism Crisis 30 ...EduSkills OECD
 
CARE OF CHILD IN INCUBATOR..........pptx
CARE OF CHILD IN INCUBATOR..........pptxCARE OF CHILD IN INCUBATOR..........pptx
CARE OF CHILD IN INCUBATOR..........pptxGaneshChakor2
 
PSYCHIATRIC History collection FORMAT.pptx
PSYCHIATRIC   History collection FORMAT.pptxPSYCHIATRIC   History collection FORMAT.pptx
PSYCHIATRIC History collection FORMAT.pptxPoojaSen20
 
Separation of Lanthanides/ Lanthanides and Actinides
Separation of Lanthanides/ Lanthanides and ActinidesSeparation of Lanthanides/ Lanthanides and Actinides
Separation of Lanthanides/ Lanthanides and ActinidesFatimaKhan178732
 

Recently uploaded (20)

Concept of Vouching. B.Com(Hons) /B.Compdf
Concept of Vouching. B.Com(Hons) /B.CompdfConcept of Vouching. B.Com(Hons) /B.Compdf
Concept of Vouching. B.Com(Hons) /B.Compdf
 
Science 7 - LAND and SEA BREEZE and its Characteristics
Science 7 - LAND and SEA BREEZE and its CharacteristicsScience 7 - LAND and SEA BREEZE and its Characteristics
Science 7 - LAND and SEA BREEZE and its Characteristics
 
Model Call Girl in Bikash Puri Delhi reach out to us at 🔝9953056974🔝
Model Call Girl in Bikash Puri  Delhi reach out to us at 🔝9953056974🔝Model Call Girl in Bikash Puri  Delhi reach out to us at 🔝9953056974🔝
Model Call Girl in Bikash Puri Delhi reach out to us at 🔝9953056974🔝
 
Mastering the Unannounced Regulatory Inspection
Mastering the Unannounced Regulatory InspectionMastering the Unannounced Regulatory Inspection
Mastering the Unannounced Regulatory Inspection
 
Crayon Activity Handout For the Crayon A
Crayon Activity Handout For the Crayon ACrayon Activity Handout For the Crayon A
Crayon Activity Handout For the Crayon A
 
POINT- BIOCHEMISTRY SEM 2 ENZYMES UNIT 5.pptx
POINT- BIOCHEMISTRY SEM 2 ENZYMES UNIT 5.pptxPOINT- BIOCHEMISTRY SEM 2 ENZYMES UNIT 5.pptx
POINT- BIOCHEMISTRY SEM 2 ENZYMES UNIT 5.pptx
 
A Critique of the Proposed National Education Policy Reform
A Critique of the Proposed National Education Policy ReformA Critique of the Proposed National Education Policy Reform
A Critique of the Proposed National Education Policy Reform
 
Sanyam Choudhary Chemistry practical.pdf
Sanyam Choudhary Chemistry practical.pdfSanyam Choudhary Chemistry practical.pdf
Sanyam Choudhary Chemistry practical.pdf
 
Introduction to AI in Higher Education_draft.pptx
Introduction to AI in Higher Education_draft.pptxIntroduction to AI in Higher Education_draft.pptx
Introduction to AI in Higher Education_draft.pptx
 
Alper Gobel In Media Res Media Component
Alper Gobel In Media Res Media ComponentAlper Gobel In Media Res Media Component
Alper Gobel In Media Res Media Component
 
Hybridoma Technology ( Production , Purification , and Application )
Hybridoma Technology  ( Production , Purification , and Application  ) Hybridoma Technology  ( Production , Purification , and Application  )
Hybridoma Technology ( Production , Purification , and Application )
 
How to Make a Pirate ship Primary Education.pptx
How to Make a Pirate ship Primary Education.pptxHow to Make a Pirate ship Primary Education.pptx
How to Make a Pirate ship Primary Education.pptx
 
Introduction to ArtificiaI Intelligence in Higher Education
Introduction to ArtificiaI Intelligence in Higher EducationIntroduction to ArtificiaI Intelligence in Higher Education
Introduction to ArtificiaI Intelligence in Higher Education
 
Call Girls in Dwarka Mor Delhi Contact Us 9654467111
Call Girls in Dwarka Mor Delhi Contact Us 9654467111Call Girls in Dwarka Mor Delhi Contact Us 9654467111
Call Girls in Dwarka Mor Delhi Contact Us 9654467111
 
Paris 2024 Olympic Geographies - an activity
Paris 2024 Olympic Geographies - an activityParis 2024 Olympic Geographies - an activity
Paris 2024 Olympic Geographies - an activity
 
Industrial Policy - 1948, 1956, 1973, 1977, 1980, 1991
Industrial Policy - 1948, 1956, 1973, 1977, 1980, 1991Industrial Policy - 1948, 1956, 1973, 1977, 1980, 1991
Industrial Policy - 1948, 1956, 1973, 1977, 1980, 1991
 
Presentation by Andreas Schleicher Tackling the School Absenteeism Crisis 30 ...
Presentation by Andreas Schleicher Tackling the School Absenteeism Crisis 30 ...Presentation by Andreas Schleicher Tackling the School Absenteeism Crisis 30 ...
Presentation by Andreas Schleicher Tackling the School Absenteeism Crisis 30 ...
 
CARE OF CHILD IN INCUBATOR..........pptx
CARE OF CHILD IN INCUBATOR..........pptxCARE OF CHILD IN INCUBATOR..........pptx
CARE OF CHILD IN INCUBATOR..........pptx
 
PSYCHIATRIC History collection FORMAT.pptx
PSYCHIATRIC   History collection FORMAT.pptxPSYCHIATRIC   History collection FORMAT.pptx
PSYCHIATRIC History collection FORMAT.pptx
 
Separation of Lanthanides/ Lanthanides and Actinides
Separation of Lanthanides/ Lanthanides and ActinidesSeparation of Lanthanides/ Lanthanides and Actinides
Separation of Lanthanides/ Lanthanides and Actinides
 

Nancy Folbre unproductive-housewife (1991)

  • 1. The Unproductive Housewife: Her Evolution in Nineteenth-Century Economic Thought Author(s): Nancy Folbre Source: Signs, Vol. 16, No. 3 (Spring, 1991), pp. 463-484 Published by: The University of Chicago Press Stable URL: http://www.jstor.org/stable/3174585 Accessed: 28-05-2017 11:03 UTC REFERENCES Linked references are available on JSTOR for this article: http://www.jstor.org/stable/3174585?seq=1&cid=pdf-reference#references_tab_contents You may need to log in to JSTOR to access the linked references. JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide range of content in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and facilitate new forms of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact support@jstor.org. Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available at http://about.jstor.org/terms The University of Chicago Press is collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend access to Signs This content downloaded from 154.59.124.94 on Sun, 28 May 2017 11:03:11 UTC All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
  • 2. THE UNPRODUCTIVE HOUSEWIFE: HER EVOLUTION IN NINETEENTH- CENTURY ECONOMIC THOUGHT NANCY FOLBRE In 1878 the officers of the Association for the Advancement of Women (AAW) protested the U.S. Census's notion that "home- keepers" were not gainful workers. In a letter to Congress they wrote, "We pray your honorable body to make provision for the more careful and just enumeration of women as laborers and producers." They complained that women's domestic efforts were "not even incidentally named as in any wise affecting the causes of increase or decrease of population or wealth."' (See Appendix.) In short, the AAW quarreled with the official assumption that house- wives were unproductive workers because they earned no pay. Census data consist of ordered sets of numbers. They appear objective and value free, but their meaning grows out of socially constructed concepts that are laden with cultural and political values. "Statistical reports exemplify the process by which visions My collaboration with Marjorie Abel on related topics inspired this article; Margo Anderson kept me going. Daniel Scott Smith provided many helpful suggestions, including one that led me to the expertise of archivist Susan Grigg, director of the Sophia Smith Collection at Smith College. David Alexander, Donald McCloskey, and Robert Solow offered invaluable encouragement. Two anonymous reviewers of Signs suggested important revisions in the exposition of the arguments. Thanks to all. Memorial of Mary F. Eastman, Henrietta L. T. Woolcott, and others ... Senate Miscellaneous Documents, 45th Congress, 2d Session, vol. 2, no. 84 (Serial Set, 1786). For full text, see Appendix. [Signs: Journal of Women in Culture and Society 1991, vol. 16, no. 3] ? 1991 by The University of Chicago. All rights reserved. 0097-9740/91/1603-0002$01.00 463 This content downloaded from 154.59.124.94 on Sun, 28 May 2017 11:03:11 UTC All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
  • 3. Folbre / UNPRODUCTIVE HOUSEWIFE of reality, models of social structure, were elaborated and revised," writes Joan Scott.2 Other recent feminist scholarship details the androcentric focus of many conventional census categories.3 Gender bias in the definition of economically productive activity has important implications for the analysis of changes in female labor-force participation. One aspect of such gender bias-the con- cept of the unproductive housewife-gradually coalesced in the nineteenth-century censuses of population in England and the United States. In 1800, women whose work consisted largely of caring for their families were considered productive workers. By 1900, they had been formally relegated to the census category of "dependents," a category that included infants, young children, the sick, and the elderly. Several factors shaped the changing attitudes toward household labor during the nineteenth century. A new enthusiasm for female domesticity soothed apprehensions about the impact of capitalist development on the family, and the growth of paid domestic service relieved upper-class women from the most onerous domestic chores. But gender interests were also influential. When male trade unionists argued that hardworking housewives were-or should be-"dependents," they obscured the benefits men enjoyed from women's domestic labor. Political economists and statisticians played an important role in the deployment of a new vocabulary that complemented the idealization of family life and men's demands for a family wage. While they seldom explicitly discussed household labor, they addressed related topics, and their influence on official terminology can be traced through the evolution of census categories. In Great Britain, the initial assumption that housewives were gainful work- ers was gradually displaced, with the assistance of economist Alfred Marshall. The prominent Francis Amasa Walker, who took charge of the U.S. census after the Civil War, ignored the productive contri- butions of housewives, despite strong feminist criticisms. In Mas- sachusetts, the liberal Carroll Wright encouraged attention to 2 Joan Scott, "A Statistical Representation of Work," in her Gender and History (New York: Columbia University Press, 1988), 113-38, esp. 115. 3 In addition to Scott, see Desley Deacon, "Political Arithmetic: The Nineteenth Century Australian Census and the Construction of the Dependent Woman," Signs: Journal of Women in Culture and Society 11, no. 1 (Autumn 1985): 27-47; Margo Anderson, The American Census: A Social History (New Haven, Conn.: Yale University Press, 1988); Marilyn Waring, If Women Counted: A New Feminist Economics (New York: Harper & Row, 1988); Nancy Folbre and Marjorie Abel, "Women's Work and Women's Households: Gender Bias in the U.S. Census," Social Research 56, no. 3 (Autumn 1989): 545-70. 464 This content downloaded from 154.59.124.94 on Sun, 28 May 2017 11:03:11 UTC All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
  • 4. Spring 1991 / SIGNS household work, but the census in his state gradually, if reluctantly, relinquished the concept of the productive housewife. Domesticity and devaluation Praise of domesticity and the unique character of the family home played a widely recognized role in nineteenth-century social thought. The "cult of domesticity" contributed to the emergence of a distinctively female culture and became an important strand of nineteenth-century feminism. While feminist scholarship has fo- cused on the social and cultural aspects of this phenomenon, the economic implications have been largely ignored.4 Ironically, the moral elevation of the home was accompanied by the economic devaluation of the work performed there. The growth of wage labor, which separated individuals from traditional family- based productive units, almost inevitably wrought new concepts of productive labor. Goods that could be bought and sold, quantities that could be expressed in dollar terms, became the new arbiters of value. Indeed, the growing enthusiasm for social statistics, re- flected in new census-taking efforts, deflected attention from activ- ities that could not easily be reduced to a money metric. Over the course of the nineteenth century, work once performed within patriarchal households under the authority of fathers and husbands was gradually, but only partially, supplanted by the growth of an impersonal marketplace in which the labor power of individuals was bought and sold like any other commodity. Single women entered the paid labor force in large numbers, but most left upon marriage. As late as 1900, 40 percent of single women, but only 6 percent of married women, over age ten in the United States were designated "occupied" by the U.S. Census. In England and Wales in 1901, about 10 percent of married women were listed with occupations.5 These figures understate the contributions that women made to their families' economic welfare. Numerous social historical stud- ies show that married women not only performed domestic labor 4 Barbara Welter, "The Cult of True Womanhood," American Quarterly 18, no. 2 (1966): 151-74; Linda Kerber, "Separate Spheres, Female Worlds, Woman's Place: The Rhetoric of Women's History," Journal of American History 75, no. 1 (June 1988): 9-39. 5 Twelfth Census of the United States: 1900, Special Reports, Supplementary Analysis and Derivative Tables (Washington, D.C.: Government Printing Office); Census of England and Wales, 1901. 465 This content downloaded from 154.59.124.94 on Sun, 28 May 2017 11:03:11 UTC All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
  • 5. Folbre / UNPRODUCTIVE HOUSEWIFE but also garnered significant amounts of market income.6 The wives of farmers, merchants, and craftsmen participated in family enterprises. Many women took in boarders and lodgers, exchanging household services such as cooking and cleaning for money. Housewives pro- vided their own families with an even wider range of domestic services-meal preparation, laundry, child rearing, care of the sick and elderly, household management, and general nurturance. During the late eighteenth and early nineteenth centuries, domestic work was recognized as a productive and valuable con- tribution. Despite a strict sexual division of labor, many men as well as women produced goods and services for household use, includ- ing housing, furniture, and food grown for the family table. As male participation in the market economy expanded, however, produc- tion for use rather than exchange became identified as a distinctly female activity.7 The home was often described in feminine terms- stable, reassuring, altruistic. The market, by contrast, was a mascu- line, dynamic realm, characterized by competition and the pursuit of economic self-interest. A new emphasis on domestic virtue, rather than domestic work, was rooted in genuine fears about the impact of a new emphasis on profits and personal gain that conflicted with traditional religious values. Catherine Beecher's Treatise on Domestic Economy, first published in 1841, strictly banished the logic of economic self- interest and laissez-faire from the home. The great mission of the "family state," she wrote, "is self denial and in training its members to self-sacrificing labors for the ignorant and weak."8 Beecher consistently argued that women's allegiance to home and family was a necessary counterbalance to the competitive anarchy of the market economy.9 6 Alice Clark, Working Life of Women in the Seventeenth Century (1919; reprint, New York: Kelley, 1967); Edith Abbott, Women in Industry: A Study in American Economic History (1910; reprint, New York: Appleton, 1924); Joan Jensen, Loosen- ing the Bonds: Mid-Atlantic Farm Women, 1750-1850 (New Haven, Conn.: Yale University Press, 1986); Claudia Goldin, "The Female Labor Force and American Economic Growth, 1890-1980," in Long-Term Factors in American Economic Growth, ed. Stanley L. Engerman and Robert E. Gallman, National Bureau of Economic Research Studies in Income and Wealth, vol. 51 (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1986), 557-604. 7 Glenna Matthews, Just a Housewife: The Rise and Fall of Domesticity in America (New York: Oxford University Press, 1987); Ruth Schwartz Cowan, More Workfor Mother: The Ironies of Household Technologyfrom the Open Hearth to the Microwave (New York: Basic, 1983). 8 Catherine Beecher, A Treatise on Domestic Economy (1841; reprint, New York: Source Book Press, 1974), 19. 9 Kathryn Kish Sklar, Catherine Beecher: A Study in American Domesticity (New York: Norton, 1976). 466 This content downloaded from 154.59.124.94 on Sun, 28 May 2017 11:03:11 UTC All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
  • 6. Spring 1991 / SIGNS She developed her philosophy further in The American Wom- an's Home, published in 1869 and coauthored with her sister, Harriet Beecher Stowe.?' The book embodies the contradictory character of Victorian domesticity. On the one hand, it provides a wealth of technical details regarding the efficient management and performance of household labor. On the other hand, it treats this work as a moral responsibility, not an economically important activity that might be organized along different, less gendered lines. This was family labor, not domestic labor-its aim, the fulfillment of God-given responsibilities, not economic efficiency; its motive not self-interest, but love. Most political economists reinforced this distinction between the moral (or private) and the economic (or public) world, neatly assigning women and the family to one, men and the market to the other." Even the prominent English neoclassicals, well known for their emphasis on the competitive marketplace, were reluctant to allow economic self-interest to disrupt the home. Stanley Jevons, an otherwise loyal advocate of laissez-faire, proposed that mothers with children under age three should be banned from factories and workshops.'2 Alfred Marshall cautioned against increases in wom- en's wages that might tempt wives and mothers to neglect their household duties.l3 Growing class differences also contributed to a new view of married women's roles. The "lady," long the ideal of English aristocratic society, began to supplant the housewife as a cultural ideal in the United States during the 1830s.14 With the increased availability of domestic servants, middle- and upper-class families redefined the role of wives, emphasizing their qualities of personal nurturance and their civilizing influence on husbands and children. By 1880, more than fifteen domestic servants were enumerated per 100 families in many major cities.'5 10 Catherine Beecher and Harriet Beecher Stowe, The American Woman's Home (New York: J. B. Ford, 1869). " Nancy Folbre and Heidi Hartmann, "The Rhetoric of SelfInterest and the Ideology of Gender," in The Consequences of Economic Rhetoric, ed. Arjo Klamer, Donald Mc- Closkey, and Robert Solow (New York: Cambridge University Press, 1988), 184-206. 12 Stanley Jevons, "Married Women in Factories," in Methods of Social Reform and Other Papers (London: Macmillan, 1883). "3 Alfred Marshall, Principles of Economics, 8th ed. (London: Macmillan, 1930: 685, 715. 14 Sarah Eisenstein, Give Us Bread but Give Us Roses: Working Women's Consciousness in the United States, 1890 to the First World War (Boston: Routledge & Kegan Paul, 1983). 15 David Katzman, Seven Days a Week: Women and Domestic Service in Indus- trial America (New York: Oxford University Press, 1978), 286. See also Faye 467 This content downloaded from 154.59.124.94 on Sun, 28 May 2017 11:03:11 UTC All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
  • 7. Folbre / UNPRODUCTIVE HOUSEWIFE Victorian culture promoted new, refined ideals that working- class women, busy keeping their families fed and clothed, could seldom afford.16 Yet these ideals proved appealing partly because they helped stabilize a traditional patriarchal system that was being shaken by women's new economic opportunities outside the home. Wally Seccombe persuasively describes the emergence of the "male breadwinner norm" in England as an expression of the economic interests of skilled male trade unionists who feared competition from women who would work for a lower wage.'7 Me also benefited economically from the cheap domestic services t women provided for them in the home.'8 In both England and the United States, predominantly ma trade unions couched their demands in terms of a "family wa that only men should earn.'9 Economic vocabulary played important part in such arguments. Consider the words of a memb of the National Typographer's Union who protested the seating Susan B. Anthony at a National Labor Union Conference in 186 "The lady goes in for taking women away from the wash tub, and the name of heaven, who is going there, if they don't? I believe in a woman's doing her work, men marrying them and support them."20 The gentleman's concern with his laundry hints at t stake men had in reinforcing women's domestic responsibilitie self-interest that this speaker obscured with the concept of m economic "support." When male trade unionists argued that th should earn enough money so their wives would not have to wo Dudden, Household Service in Nineteenth-Century America (Middletown, Co Wesleyan University Press, 1983); and Theresa McBride, The Domestic Revolut The Modernization of Household Service in England and France, 1820-1920 (N York: Holmes & Meier, 1976). 16 Gerda Lerner, "The Lady and the Mill Girl: Changes in the Status of Wom in the Age of Jackson," Midcontinent American Studies Journal 10, no. 1 (Spr 1969): 5-15. 17 Wally Seccombe, "Patriarchy Stabilized: The Construction of the Male Bre winner Wage Norm in Nineteenth-Century Britain," Social History 2, no. 1 (Janua 1986): 53-76. 18 Heidi Hartmann, "Capitalism, Patriarchy, and Job Segregation by Sex," Signs 1, no. 3 (Spring 1976): 137-69; Phillip Foner, Women and the American Labor Movement: From Colonial Times to the Eve of World War I (New York: Free Press, 1979); Sonia Rose, "Gender and Work: Sex, Class and Industrial Capitalism," History Workshop Journal 21 (Spring 1986): 557-604; Sidney Webb, "Women's Wages," in Problems of Modern Industry, by Sidney Webb and Beatrice Webb (New York: Longmans Green, 1989), 46-81. 19 Martha May, "Bread before Roses: American Workingmen, Labor Unions and the Family Wage," in Women, Work and Protest: A Century of U.S. Women's Labor History, ed. Ruth Milkman (Boston: Routledge & Kegan Paul, 1985), 113-31. 20 Foner, 136. 468 This content downloaded from 154.59.124.94 on Sun, 28 May 2017 11:03:11 UTC All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
  • 8. Spring 1991 / SIGNS they clearly defined "work" as labor performed outside the home for wages. By describing themselves as the sole support of the family, men undervalued the services they received in return for the wages they contributed. The exaltation of domestic virtue, growing class inequalities, patriarchal interests-all of these factors contributed to new char- acterizations of household labor. But the most specific evidence of literal devaluation lies in the history of Anglo-American political economy. In both theory and practice, this emerging science showed a distinct tendency to treat women's household work in moral rather than economic terms. The result was a new statistical categorization of housewives that gradually found expression in the censuses of population. England and Wales England was home to the classics of political economy, and her censuses provided a model for the data-gathering practices of her colonies and, later, her Commonwealth. Unlike the United States, where the Constitution mandated a decennial census that helped determine political representation, the early censuses of Great Britain were incorporated into the existing vital registry system and, as such, were heavily influenced by medical concerns such as the measurement of infant mortality.21 Perhaps as a result, early census practices reflected physicians' appreciation of the difficul- ties of rearing children, rather than economists' lack of interest in such forms of work. From the very outset, political economy was preoccupied with the distinction between productive and unproductive labor. In the eighteenth century, the French Physiocrats suggested that agricul- ture was the only true source of surplus and described profits earned in manufacturing as a mere redistribution. But the Scottish economist Adam Smith offered a spirited defense of manufacturing and called for a new definition of productive labor, based on the addition of "net value" to a vendible commodity.22 He argued that services were unproductive because they did not contribute to the accumulation of physical wealth. Domestic servants, for example, merely enhanced their employers' standard of living. 21 J. M. Eyler, Victorian Social Medicine: The Ideas and Methods of William Farr (Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press, 1979). 2 Mark Blaug, Economic Theory in Retrospect, 4th ed. (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1985). 469 This content downloaded from 154.59.124.94 on Sun, 28 May 2017 11:03:11 UTC All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
  • 9. Folbre / UNPRODUCTIVE HOUSEWIFE Smith used the term "productive" primarily to distinguish activities that he believed contributed to economic growth. Most of his immediate successors in the field, including David Ricardo, Thomas Robert Malthus, and John Stuart Mill, followed suit. But none agreed completely with the terms of Smith's definitions. Mill, in particular, argued that some services, such as the training of workers, contributed to economic growth and should be deemed productive.23 Partly because the issue was never resolved, the classical dichotomy between productive and unproductive labor was gradually replaced by a new distinction between market and nonmarket labor. By the end of the nineteenth century, most economists had come to agree that all paid services should be considered productive, and many advocated that the term "unproductive" be dropped from the language of their discipline.24 Yet, almost to a man, they also agreed that nonmarket services lay outside the realm of economics and therefore did not contribute to economic growth. While paid domestic servants were considered part of the labor force, unpaid domestic workers were not. Nonmarket production-a wife's work in the home, for instance-was implicitly defined as unproductive. This sharp distinction between the household and the market was not reflected in the early censuses of Great Britain. Following an unsuccessful attempt in 1801 to collect information on the occupations of individuals, the censuses of 1811, 1821, and 1831 inquired after the occupations of families as productive units. As Catherine Hakim points out, "The idea of an individual male wage-earner supporting his family was unfamiliar in the first half of the nineteenth century. It was assumed that all members of the household contributed to the family enterprise in agriculture, trade, or handicraft (unless they had independent means)."25 In 1831 occupations of males age twenty or older were enumerated sepa- rately, as were those of female servants of all ages. In 1851, for the first time, general female occupations were enumerated.26 The list of categories to which they could be assigned included nonmarket household work as well as paid occupations such as teacher or dressmaker. 3 William J. Barber, A History of Economic Thought (New York: Penguin, 1979), 97. 24 Joseph Schumpeter, History of Economic Analysis (New York: Oxford Univer- sity Press, 1954), 628; The New Palgrave: A Dictionary of Economics, ed. John Eatwell, Murray Milgate, and Peter Newman (London: Macmillan, 1987), 1008. 25 Catherine Hakim, "Census Reports as Documentary Evidence: The Census Commentaries, 1801-1951," Sociological Review 28, no. 3 (August 1980): 551-80, esp. 554. 26 Census of Great Britain, 1851, vol. 1, Population, British Parliamentary Papers (Dublin: Irish University Press, 1970), Ixix. 470 This content downloaded from 154.59.124.94 on Sun, 28 May 2017 11:03:11 UTC All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
  • 10. Spring 1991 / SIGNS Under the influence of the physician William Farr, the 1851 census placed "wives, mothers and mistresses" in a category by themselves, the "Fifth Class" among the occupations. Women with occupations outside the home were grouped accordingly in differ- ent classes. Still another class (the "Seventeenth," to be precise) was reserved for "dependents," or those supported by the commu- nity: "children, the sick and infirm, gypsies and vagrants, and certain ladies and gentlemen of independent means."27 The official discussion of the tabulations conveyed a strong appreciation of domestic work: "The most important production of a country is its population."2 The text went on to deplore women's employment outside the home. In their critical analyses of the early English censuses, Desley Deacon and Edward Higgs both emphasize the influence of Farr's medical orientation.29 But Farr was by no means immune to the predominant opinions of political economists. The tenor of the discussion of women's work in the census volumes he supervised changed over time. In the 1861 Census of England and Wales, wives and widows "not otherwise described" were included in class 2, the "Domestic Class," along with scholars, paid domestic workers, entertainers, and people who performed personal ser- vices, such as barbers. But the census discussion seemed somewhat apologetic: "These women are sometimes returned as of no occu- pation. But the occupation of wife and mother and housewife is the most important in the country, as will be immediately apparent if it be assumed for a moment to be suppressed."30 The 1871 census used similar categories, but more openly confronted its nomenclatural dilemma. The notes comment that the occupation of wife and mother is "a noble and essential" one, but they also call attention to the increase in women's factory employ- ment, a rapid increase in "the proportion of women engaged specifically in productive work."31 The language suggests that unpaid domestic labor, however noble, was not truly productive. Still, the suggestion remained just that; wives and mothers could have been but were not included in the new category termed "Indefinite and Non-productive," which included people without 27 Celia Davies, "Making Sense of the Census in Britain and the U.S.A.: The Changing Occupational Classification and the Position of Nurses," Sociological Review 28, no. 3 (August 1980): 581-609. 28 Census of Great Britain, 1851, lxxxviii. 29 Deacon (n. 3 above); see also Edward Higgs, "Women, Occupations, and Work in the Nineteenth-Century Censuses," History Workshop 23 (Spring 1987): 59-80. 30 Census of England and Wales, 1861 and 1871, British Parliamentary Papers (Dublin: Irish University Press, 1970) 33. 31 Ibid., xlii. 471 This content downloaded from 154.59.124.94 on Sun, 28 May 2017 11:03:11 UTC All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
  • 11. Folbre / UNPRODUCTIVE HOUSEWIFE specified occupations and those whose occupations were described in general or vague terms. William Farr retired shortly after the 1871 census appeared, and terminology shifted more decisively in the 1881 census. Wives and other women engaged in domestic duties were explicitly placed in the "Unoccupied Class," which apparently replaced the earlier "Indefinite and Non-productive" category. The discussion noted that many of the "unoccupied" were women, "of whom by far the greater part were married and engaged in the management of domestic life, and who can only be called unoccupied, when that term is used in the limited sense that it bears in the Census Returns. Many more of these women, though unmarried, were also engaged in domestic duties, or were assisting their fathers or other near relatives in the details of business.""32 Having previously apologized for counting wives and mothers occupied, the registry now apologized for doing just the opposite. In 1890, a parliamentary committee was convened to consider improvements to the census. The prominent neoclassical econo- mist Alfred Marshall, who was called to testify, held up a recent German census as an example of superior methodology. Marshall complained that the English occupational categories failed to explain the distinctions between skilled and unskilled labor.33 He was also dissatisfied with the large numbers in the "Unoccupied" column and urged the committee to eliminate it. "In other coun- tries," he explained, "you see the dependents upon anybody who is occupied are entered as dependent, and therefore the figures in this column (unoccupied) are very small."34 Marshall clearly agreed with the German convention of describ- ing married women as "dependents," a description far more con- sistent with the tradition of English political economy than previous census practices. According to the diaries of the prominent socia reformer Beatrice Webb, who opposed women's suffrage at the time she met him, Marshall strongly disliked and disapproved of the prospect of female independence.35 His classic Principles of Eco- 32 Census of England and Wales, 1881, British Parliamentary Papers (Dublin: Irish University Press, 1970), 63. 33 Report of the Committee Appointed by the Treasury to Inquire into Certain Questions Connected with the Taking of the Census, British Parliamentary Papers (c. 6071), LVIII, 13, 68. 34 Ibid., 66. 35 Glitter Around and Darkness Within, vol. 1 (1873-92) of The Diary of Beatrice Webb, ed. Norman and Jeanne McKenzie (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1982), 273. The entire passage follows: "Conversation with Professor Mar- shall, he holding that woman was a subordinate being, and that, if she ceased to be subordinate, there would be no object for a man to marry, that marriage was a sacrifice of the masculine freedom and would only be tolerated by male creatures so 472 This content downloaded from 154.59.124.94 on Sun, 28 May 2017 11:03:11 UTC All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
  • 12. Spring 1991 / SIGNS nomics mentioned only in passing the problematic character of the new definition of productive labor: "There is however some incon- sistency in omitting the heavy domestic work which is done by women and other members of the household, where no servants are kept."36 At least one of Marshall's lesser-known contemporaries devoted slightly more attention to the economic significance of women's household work: "What this income really amounts to may be guessed if we imagine what we should have to pay to servants for doing work now done by wives, sisters, and daughters, and how entirely impossible it would be to get similar work done for money," wrote economist William Smart. "If such women went to the factory or into professional life, we should have to withdraw probably a much greater number from the factory or professions to take their place, and should lose something with it all."37 Unfortu- nately, by the time Smart registered these concerns, a new census terminology had limited the prospects for empirically assessing them. In 1891 the Census of England and Wales restricted the "Do- mestic Class" to those employed in paid domestic service. The "Unoccupied Class" simply disappeared from the categories, as Marshall had recommended. Polite mention was still made of wives and mothers: "The most important, however, of all female occupa- tions ... is altogether omitted from the reckoning, namely the rearing of children and the management of domestic life." If these were included, the notes continue, the proportion of occupied women would approach that of men.38 Australia, a major Commonwealth country, shifted its terminol- ogy in a similar way in 1890. Advocates of a clear emphasis on men as "breadwinners" and women as "dependents" won a decisive victory when, in the absence of a clear statement to the contrary, long as it meant the devotion, body and mind, of the female and no longer. Hence the woman must develop in no way unpleasant to the man: that strength, courage, independence were not attractive in women, that rivalry in men's pursuits was positively unpleasant. Therefore masculine strength and masculine ability in women must be firmly trampled on and 'boycotted' by men. Contrast was the essence of the matrimonial relation: feminine weakness contrasted with masculine strength, masculine egotism with feminine self-devotion. Naturally enough I main- tained the opposite argument; viz. that there was an ideal of character in which strength, courage, sympathy, self-devotion, persistent purpose were united to a clear and far-seeing intellect: that this ideal was common to the man and the woman." 3 Marshall (n. 13 above), 80. 37 William Smart, The Distribution of Income (New York: Macmillan, 1899), 69. 38 Census of England and Wales, 1891, British Parliamentary Papers (Dublin: Irish University Press), 58. 473 This content downloaded from 154.59.124.94 on Sun, 28 May 2017 11:03:11 UTC All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
  • 13. Folbre / UNPRODUCTIVE HOUSEWIFE women's work was classified as domestic and they were labeled "de- pendents." The chief director of the New South Wales census "argued that both women's contributions to family economies and their com- petition for jobs lowered the wages of men and the community's stan- dard of living."39 National statistics showing a low rate of female labor- force participation would, he believed, enhance Australia's image as a prosperous colony worthy of English investment. The United States The grand tradition of English political economy shaped the U federal censuses from the outset. The lack of connection with a vi statistics registry may have deflected attention from child rearin and other domestic activities. The standard occupational categor consistently ignored women's household labor, and protests b feminists, however articulate, had no apparent impact. In the United States, political economists never fully endors Smith's distinction between productive and unproductive labor Yet they were remarkably unanimous in their low opinion women's capacity for important work. The absence of discussi before the 1880s was perhaps more significant than the few remar that were made. Noteworthy, however, was the well-known politi- cal economist Amasa Walker's insistence that women's wages should be low because "the prevailing ideas of the community restrict them to easily dispensible occupations."41 The eminent southerner Thomas Dew held that women's qualities of mind fitted them for subservient roles.42 Such ideas had little discernible influence on the early censuses of population, which, as in England and Wales, focused on families rather than individuals. In 1820, the first year that economic activities became a topic of concern, the federal census tallied the number of families engaged in agriculture, commerce, and manu- facturing.43 The 1830 census included no reference to occupations, but the 1840 census basically followed the 1820 format. 39 Deacon (n. 3 above), 35. 40 Paul K. Conkin, Prophets of Prosperity: America's First Political Economists (Bloomington: Indiana University Press, 1980), 147. 41 Joseph Dorfman, The Economic Mind in American Civilization (New York: Kelley, 1969), 750. 42 Ibid., 908. 43 Still, even at this early date "household manufactures" were explicitly distin- guished from others as "only incidental, and not the profession properly marking the class of society to which such individual belongs." These words, attributed to John Quincy Adams, suggests that the census was more interested in "properly marking" class (broadly construed to include the class of housewives) rather than counting the 474 This content downloaded from 154.59.124.94 on Sun, 28 May 2017 11:03:11 UTC All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
  • 14. Spring 1991 / SIGNS As industrial employment grew, so did interest in individual occupations. In 1850 the census inquired after the "profession, occupation, or trade of each male person over 15 years of age."44 In 1860 and thereafter, this inquiry was extended to women. Unlike the Census of England and Wales, the U.S. Census did not officially recognize the occupation of housewife. The influence of political economic theory became particularly apparent in 1870, when Francis Amasa Walker, son of Amasa Walker, took charge of the census. Of all the nineteenth-century stewards of official statistics, Walker was by far the most academi- cally prestigious. President of the Massachusetts Institute of Tech- nology, he also presided over the American Economics Association from 1885 to 1892.45 Under his aegis, the census explicitly stipulated a wage/salary criterion for women's occupations: "The term 'housekeeper' will be reserved for such persons as receive distinct wages or salary for the service. Women keeping house for their own families or for themselves, without any other gainful occupation, will be entered as 'keeping house.' "46 This wording implies that keeping house was a gainful occupation, despite its lack of inclusion in the aggregate tabulations. Francis Walker supported women's right to vote and argued that they should have greater access to jobs outside the home-to a degree. Like his father, who described women as "incapable of self support," Walker had a low opinion of women's productive capac- ities.47 His views on the family were distinctly Malthusian. Men undertook the support of women in "obedience to a natural instinct second only, in the demand it makes on men, to the craving for food."48 Having distinguished himself in the Civil War, Walker was often addressed as "General." His description of women's assigned role in primitive economies reads like a list of military directives: "She will spin and weave... she will bring water.... She will true extent of manufacturing. See Carroll Wright, The History and Growth of the U.S. Census (Washington, D.C.: Government Printing Office, 1900), 135. 44 Ibid., 147. 45 James Phinney Munroe, A Life of Francis Amasa Walker (New York: Henry Holt, 1923), 328; Robert Solow, "What Do We Know That Francis Amasa Walker Didn't?" History of Political Economy 19, no. 2 (Summer 1987): 183-90. 6 Wright, The History and Growth of the U.S. Census, 159. 47 Amasa Walker, The Science of Wealth, A Manual of Political Economy, Embracing the Laws of Trade, Currency, and Finance (1874; reprint, Boston: Little, Brown, 1969). 48 Francis Walker, Political Economy (1883; reprint, New York: Henry Holt, 1911), 297. 475 This content downloaded from 154.59.124.94 on Sun, 28 May 2017 11:03:11 UTC All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
  • 15. Folbre / UNPRODUCTIVE HOUSEWIFE keep the hut or tent in a certain order and decency." He went on t make it absolutely clear that women in such economies were no productive workers: "We may assume that speaking broadly, sh does not produce as much as she consumes."49 Walker's conviction that women's household work was unpro ductive spilled over into the census's measurement of women's participation in the market economy. By Walker's own accoun women with occupations outside the home were underenumerate He attributed this largely to social custom and enumerator bias. the 1870 U.S. Census, Walker wrote, "it is taken for granted th every man has an occupation, and the examination of tens o thousands of pages of schedules returned in the present census has satisfied the superintendent that only in rare cases . . . have assi tant marshals failed to ask and obtain the occupation of men, or boy old enough to work with effect. It is precisely the other way with women and young children. The assumption is, as the fact gener ally is, that they are not engaged in remunerative employment Those who are so engaged constitute the exception, and it follow from a plain principle of human nature, that assistant marshals wi not infrequently forget or neglect to ask the question."50 Wom who took in boarders and lodgers, helped with the family farm business, or contracted industrial homework from factories we not counted among the gainfully occupied, even though they we earning money.51 The depreciation of women's domestic labor had long been a theme of feminist protest. Early socialist feminists such as William Thompson and Frances Wright raised the issue in England durin the 1830s, and so-called material feminists in the United State called for more efficient organization of domestic labor, includi collective facilities for meals that could take full advantage of new cooking technologies.52 In the 1860s, as the National Women's Suffrage Association explored the possibility of alliances with progressive trade unions, many of its members emphasized th 49 Ibid. 50 Ibid., 375. 51 For a more detailed discussion of the underenumeration of women's market work, see Christine Bose, "Devaluing Women's Work: The Undercount of Women's Employment in 1900," in Hidden Aspects of Women's Work, ed. Christine Bose, Roslyn Feldberg, and Natalie Sokoloff (New York: Praeger, 1987); and Nancy Folbre and Marjorie Abel, "Women's Work and Women's Households: Gender Bias in the U.S. Census," Social Research 56, no. 3 (Autumn 1989): 545-70. 52 Barbara Taylor, Eve and the New Jerusalem: Socialism and Feminism in the Nineteenth Century (New York: Pantheon, 1983); Dolores Hayden, The Grand Domestic Revolution: A History of Feminist Designs for American Homes, Neigh- borhoods, and Cities (Cambridge, Mass.: MIT Press, 1981). 476 This content downloaded from 154.59.124.94 on Sun, 28 May 2017 11:03:11 UTC All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
  • 16. Spring 1991 / SIGNS drudgery of household work and the exploitation of women who performed it. Elizabeth Cady Stanton declared that women's do- mestic work differed from that of men only because it was "unpaid, unsocialized, and unrelenting."53 Elizabeth Blackwell wrote, "The theory that a wife who .. . bears her fair share of the joint burdens, is yet 'supported' by her husband has been the bane of all society."54 Some progressive trade unionists within the Knights of Labor fully agreed.55 Explicit feminist criticism of the census originated with the Association for the Advancement of Women, a group founded in 1873 that included many of the most highly educated women of the day. The Commonwealth of Massachusetts was particularly well represented by Julia Ward Howe, a prominent feminist activist; Melusina Fay Pierce, famous for her advocacy of the collectiviza- tion of housework; and Maria Mitchell, a Harvard astronomer. Sometimes affectionately dubbed the "Ladies' Social Science As- sociation," the group held annual conferences throughout the 1890s and helped design the Women's Exhibit for the Centenniai Expo- sition of 1876.56 The AAW's concerns were hardly limited to the "twelve millions of American women being overlooked as laborers or producers" (see Appendix). Consonant with their own professional interests, the members pointed out that the census could improve the quality of its statistics on women and children by hiring intelligent women as enumerators. Summaries of the conference proceedings included no mention of a response until a short retrospective essay was pub- lished in 1893. Apparently, Walker had invoked the cult of domes- ticity in his own defense. Ladies themselves, he argued, were re- luctant to acknowledge that they worked for a living.57 In 1900, the U.S. Census adopted a new use for the term "breadwinner," cautioning that "it must be understood in a sense somewhat different from its usual one ... it does not include a person who has retired from practice or business or a wife or daughter living at home and assisting only in the household duties 53 The Revolution, ed. Susan B. Anthony and Elizabeth Cady Stanton (December 24, 1868), 393. 4 Cited in William Leach, True Love and Perfect Union (New York: Basic, 1980) 193. 55 Susan Levine, Labor's True Woman: Carpet Weavers, Industrialization and Labor Reform in the Gilded Age (Philadelphia: Temple University Press, 1984). 56 Leach, 292-322. 57 American Association for the Advancement of Women, Historical Account of the Association for the Advancement of Women, 1873-1893, Twenty-first Women' Congress, World's Columbian Exposition, Chicago (Dedham, Mass.: Transcrip Steam Job Print, 1893), 9. 477 This content downloaded from 154.59.124.94 on Sun, 28 May 2017 11:03:11 UTC All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
  • 17. Folbre / UNPRODUCTIVE HOUSEWIFE without pay."58 Wives and daughters without a paying job were officially designated "dependents." State censuses became increas- ingly common in the late nineteenth century, and most of them conformed to federal format and terminology.59 The Commonwealth of Massachusetts, however, proved an important exception. The Massachusetts anomaly The 1875 State Census of Massachusetts, probably the most ambi- tious of its day, collected and compiled an unusual variety of social statistics. Its complexity may have obscured its English-style cate- gorization of women's domestic work, which received little or no attention. Its terminological anomalies represent an interesting detour from federal census practices that only gradually converged with the main road. In 1875, housewives and unmarried women who performed housework without remuneration were included in the larger category of "Domestic and Personal Office," along with subcatego- ries for paid employment such as housekeepers, servants, nurses, and washerwomen. The introduction to the first volume makes it clear that a housewife's work was considered productive: "The terms non-productive and unemployed are applied to all who take no part in the work of life."60 Indeed, a separate occupational category was reserved for the "non-productive and propertied." Traces of the old-fashioned Smithian emphasis on production of material goods remained. The introductory notes observe that only occupations in agriculture, fisheries, manufacturing, and mechani- cal industries, as well as apprentices and laborers, actually pro- duced things. All services, though they may have been performed for pay, were seen as distinct from agriculture and manufacturing- and were, by implication, somewhat suspect. Married women were not automatically assumed to be housewives. Some were described as "having nothing to do but superintend the households," and there were those who did even less than that. In the census's own words, "there are 4,786 wives of heads simply ornamen- tal."6' These amounted to less than 2 percent of all wives. Twelfth Census of the United States, 1900 (n. 5 above), 225. 59 This generalization is based on scrutiny of nineteenth-century censuses from states in which more than eight censuses were taken: New York, Michigan, and Iowa, as well as the western states of Texas and Colorado. The majority of states did not conduct systematic censuses during the nineteenth century, and interest in occupational categories was limited to the most industrialized states. 60 The Census of Massachusetts: 1875 (Boston: Albert J. Wright, 1876), xlix. 61 Ibid., 1. 478 This content downloaded from 154.59.124.94 on Sun, 28 May 2017 11:03:11 UTC All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
  • 18. Spring 1991 / SIGNS The 1885 State Census of Massachusetts dropped the "non- productive and propertied" category and introduced a variety of new categories in its place, including "retired"-"those possessed of a competency, inherited or acquired, or for some reasons, do not need to be actively engaged in order to obtain a subsistence, as distinguished from those persons classified as 'dependents,' mostly in private families, who are more or less dependent upon relatives or friends for their support."62 Similarly, the term "non-productive" was reserved for "those afflicted persons, homeless children, pau- pers, prisoners, and convicts, who by reason of their disabilities, etc., have no productive occupations." This census used the terms "dependent" and "non-productive" quite restrictively. They were not used to label housewives. But the text that accompanied the tabulations in 1885 reflected a major concession to the emerging conventional wisdom. House- wives and women who performed unpaid housework, along with scholars and students, were subtracted from the total to arrive at "remunerative occupations." The definition of the word "house- wife" itself shifted away from one based on actual work performed to more general, social terms: "By housewives are meant the female heads of household, that is, the wife or some person in the family who has general charge of the domestic affairs."63 "Housework," used to describe the work of unmarried people who performed unpaid domestic labor, retained a specific meaning at least some- what independent of gender. Of 89,062 people so engaged, seventy-seven were males. The apparent contradictions persist in the 1895 Massachusetts census. Housewives and housework are tabulated in "Domestic Service," rather than in the "not gainful," "not productive," or "dependent" categories. But in 1905, the Massachusetts census surrendered its eccentricities and placed housewives and house- work in the "not gainful" class, along with scholars, students, retirees, those unemployed for twelve months, and dependents. The "Domestic and Personal Service" category was limited to those who received a wage or salary for their work. This terminological shift was discussed in the twentieth annual report of the Massachusetts Bureau of Statistics of Labor (1889), which summarized the findings of the 1885 census regarding women in industry. The lengthy explanation of why women were excluded from the "remunerative occupations" had an apologetic 62 The Census of Massachusetts: 1885, prepared under the direction of Carroll D. Wright, vol. 1, Population and Social Statistics (Boston: Wright & Potter, 1888), xxi. 63 Ibid., xxv. 479 This content downloaded from 154.59.124.94 on Sun, 28 May 2017 11:03:11 UTC All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
  • 19. Folbre / UNPRODUCTIVE HOUSEWIFE tone reminiscent of that found in the Census of England and Wales after 1880. But the discussion, far more assertive in its criticism of the conventional wisdom, anticipated William Smart's questions regarding the implicit value of unpaid domestic labor-in short what it could cost, were it paid for: To be sure, [housewives] receive no stated salary or wage, but their work is surely worth what it would cost to have it done, supposing that the housewife, as such, did no work at all. There were 372,612 housewives in Massachusetts in 1885, and only 300,999 women engaged in all other branches of industry. If a housewife were not expected nor required to work, then for the labor of 372,612 women paid service would have to be substituted. Such a demand for labor could not be supplied by the inhabitants of the State itself. Conse- quently, as the labor of the housewives was absolutely necessary to allow society to exist in its present form, the housewife is certainly "in industry." As has been stated, she is excluded from the previous tables in this Part for conven- tional and arbitrary reasons alone. The housewife is as much a member of the army of workers as the clerk or cotton weaver, and too often supplements the toil of the day, "in industry" with household duties performed at home, but outside of the "in industry" classification.4 The author of this prescient explanation remains a mystery, although Horace Wadlin, director of the Boston Public Library, was in command of the Massachusetts Bureau of Labor at the time. Responsibility for the more generous English-style terminology of the 1875 and 1885 censuses lies almost certainly with then-director Carroll Wright, who had a unique, if undeveloped, theoretical perspective on women's household work. The 1875 Massachusetts census represented his official debut as one of the most influential statisticians of the late nineteenth century. Wright, who also served as a special agent for the 1880 U.S. Census, was appointed U.S. Commissioner of Labor in 1885 and served until 1905. During his tenure, he presided over the 1890 U.S. Census and many important census-sponsored studies and reports. James Leiby's classic study of Wright's lifework describes him as an autodidact lacking in intellectual stature, who relied heavily 64 Massachusetts Bureau of Labor Statistics, Twentieth Annual Report of the Bureau of the Statistics of Labor (Boston: Wright & Potter, December 1889), 579. 480 This content downloaded from 154.59.124.94 on Sun, 28 May 2017 11:03:11 UTC All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
  • 20. Spring 1991 / SIGNS on the advice of Francis Walker.5 Yet the data that Wright collected may have had a far greater impact on subsequent economic research than Walker's theoretical or empirical contributions. Wright had an uncanny instinct for the systematic exploration of politically impor- tant issues. His classic study, The Working Girls of Boston, was one of the first efforts to examine the implications of factory employ- ment. In it, Wright argued that the length of the working day for women should be limited to ten hours in part because, according to his survey, they did much of their own domestic labor and had little time for rest.6 Wright eventually became far more sympathetic to feminism than most of his male counterparts, as evidenced by his article "Why Women Earn Less Than Men," which acknowledged the discrimination women faced.67 His Massachusetts background meant that he almost inevitably came into contact with some of the more prominent members of the Association for the Advancement of Women. But Wright's adherence to the concept of the productive housewife, though admirable, was neither strong nor persistent. His voluminous writings were largely preoccupied with relations between labor and capital. Even his published address to the American Social Science Association on "Problems of the Census" in 1887 omitted any consideration of household labor. The implications of a new terminology The censuses of England, the United States, and Massachusetts reveal the emergence of a new terminology that clearly labeled housework unproductive. What do these examples tell us about the coevolution of political economy and its more pragmatic language of measurement? The concept of the unproductive housewife was a by-product of a new definition of productive labor that valorized participation in the market and devalorized the nonmarket work central to many women's lives. The terminological shift formalized the assumptions of androcentric political economy. This shift was not unique to one country. Given Alfred Marshall's recommendation that England import the German practice of cat- 65 James Leiby, Carroll Wright and Labor Reform: The Origin of Labor Statistics (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1960). 66 Carroll Wright, "The Working Girls of Boston," Fifteenth Annual Report of the Bureau of the Statistics of Labor (Boston: Wright & Potter, July 1884), 129. 67 Carroll Wright, "Why Women Earn Less Than Men," Forum (July 1892), 629-39. 481 This content downloaded from 154.59.124.94 on Sun, 28 May 2017 11:03:11 UTC All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
  • 21. Folbre / UNPRODUCTIVE HOUSEWIFE egorizing housewives as dependents, it cannot be attributed simply to Victorian ideology writ large. Nor did the shift go unnoticed William Farr and Carroll Wright both resisted it initially. The A sociation for the Advancement of Women actively protested it. Why, then, did it not stir more discussion and debate? Part of the answer lies in the ease with which upper-class men could arrive a a comfortable consensus concerning women's capacities and con tributions. The evolution of census terminology resonates with the story that social historians have told about the functional aspects of the "breadwinner/dependent ideal."" Indeed, it suggests that his torians may have underestimated the importance of new cultur conceptions of work by failing to recognize the ways that gende bias influenced "objective" measurements of women's productive work. Political pressures influenced the way in which late nineteenth- century social statistics were collected in the United States. Th Massachusetts Bureau of Labor was created largely in response t agitation by a labor group, the Knights of Saint Crispin. The Knight of Labor successfully demanded a Federal Bureau of Labor.6 Th Divorce Reform League prompted the Federal Bureau's study o marriage and divorce statistics in the United States, which Carro Wright conducted in 1889. When Wright first assumed his respon- sibilities at the new Federal Bureau of Labor, his interest in developing a major study of African-American workers was discour- aged because of concern that southern Congressmen would be offended.70 If African-Americans or women had had more political power, even an effective right to vote, U.S. census categories might have evolved differently. A melange of theoretical, political, and practical concerns influ- enced census designers. Yet their categories, in turn, exerted tremendous influence on both everyday politics and economic theory. By 1900, the notion that married women without paying jobs outside the home were "dependents" had acquired the status of a scientific fact. Women's economic dependence commonly was used to explain their lower wages-they did not need a living wage. Indeed, men demanded a higher wage so that they might support their dependent wives.71 " See Hartmann (n. 18 above); Seccombe (n. 17 above); and Rose (n. 18 above). 69 Carroll Wright, "The Working of the Department of Labor," in Monographs on Social Economics, ed. Chas. H. Verrill (U.S. Department of Labor Exhibit, Pan American Exhibition, 1901), 1. 70 Leiby, 105. 1 Carroll Wright, The Industrial Evolution of the United States (New York: Charles Scribner's, 1901), 212; Sidney Webb (n. 18 above), 78; Barbara Meyer 482 This content downloaded from 154.59.124.94 on Sun, 28 May 2017 11:03:11 UTC All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
  • 22. Spring 1991 / SIGNS The result was a certain symmetry between private, public, and academic assumptions. The new terminology made it difficult to explain how a married man benefited from his wife's household labor or, similarly, how the larger economy benefited from nonmar- ket work. Those few scholars who remained interested in house- hold production stepped outside the traditions of political economy to found the new discipline of home economics. In that sphere, the productive housewife lived on, in theory as well as in practice. Department of Economics University of Massachusetts-Amherst Appendix Memorial of Mary F. Eastman, Henrietta L. T. Woolcott, and others, officers of the Association for the Advancement of Women, praying that the tenth census may contain a just enumeration of women as laborers and producers. To the Senate and House of Representatives of the United States in Congress assembled: Whereas the acknowledged errors, discrepancies, and incompleteness of the Ninth Census render it an unsatisfactory and unreliable record of the population, wealth, industry, and physical, mental and moral conditions of the American people; and Whereas the home and woman as a home-keeper have no place in the report, only the occupations called "gainful" being noted, and more than twelve millions of American women being overlooked as laborers or producers or left out, in common with those pursuing disreputable em- ployments, and not even incidentally named as in any wise affecting the causes or increase or decrease of population or wealth; and Whereas gross errors in enumerating the births, ages, diseases, and deaths of children are the inevitable result of the natural barriers in the way of men as collectors of social and vital statistics, who frequently obtain information, in the language of the report, from "fathers, nurses, servants, and unsympathetic fellow-boarders"; and Whereas there is obvious justice and propriety in the employment of intelligent women to collect vital statistics concerning women and chil- dren: Therefore we pray your honorable body, in enacting a law providing for the taking of the Tenth Census, to make provision for the more careful Wertheimer, We Were There: The Story of Working Women in America (New York: Pantheon, 1977), 207. 483 This content downloaded from 154.59.124.94 on Sun, 28 May 2017 11:03:11 UTC All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
  • 23. Folbre / UNPRODUCTIVE HOUSEWIFE and just enumeration of women as laborers and producers; for a record of the wages of men and women in all occupations; for a record of causes of pauperism, vagrancy, vice and crime, insanity, idiocy, blindness, deformity and disease; for the enumeration of all men and women engaged in disreputable occupations, for full statistics concerning all reformato institutions; and We further pray that you will enact such laws or amendments as may b requisite to secure the employment of a fair ratio of suitable women collectors of the centennial census. Mary T. Eastman, Massachusetts, Secretary Association for Advance- ment of Women, et al. 484 This content downloaded from 154.59.124.94 on Sun, 28 May 2017 11:03:11 UTC All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms