SlideShare a Scribd company logo
Maternity Leave and Fertility Rates
Jessica Baker
University of Alaska Anchorage
Seminar in Economic Research
Professor Lance Howe
December 10, 2015
Abstract
The aim of this paper is to determine the effect of mandated paid maternity leave
on fertility rates in ten OECD countries from 1970 to 2012. The regression analysis using
panel data for the ten countries seemed to indicate that a mandated paid maternity leave
program has no statistically significant effect on fertility rates when controlled for time
fixed effects and country fixed effects.
Introduction
While many American companies have made headlines in the last few years for
offering extensive family leave packages, the United States is one of the only countries in
the Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development (OECD) that does not
require firms to offer paid maternity leave. Though the Family and Medical Leave Act of
1993 requires employers to keep a mother’s job open for 12 weeks while she is on
maternity leave, many families may use their accrued paid leave or dig into their savings
in order to make ends meet. This stress might result in many families postponing children
or having fewer children than they would otherwise as the opportunity cost of having an
additional child may be more than they are willing to incur. However, as other developed
countries increase paid leave for both new mothers and fathers, the fertility rates in most
advanced countries continue to fall. It is the objective of this paper to investigate the
effect of the mandated policy of paid maternity leave on fertility rates in OECD
countries.
My paper will use OECD data from 1970 to 2012 on child-related leave from ten
countries combined with data from the World Bank on fertility rates, GDP per capita,
population, infant mortality rates, percent of those living in urban centers, and labor-force
participation rates. The labor-force participation rates are important to include, as the
amount of women in the labor force may explain dwindling fertility rates or may reflect a
change in maternity leave policy. Many people assume that a falling fertility rate may be
a good thing. For some countries, like Japan with a seriously declining fertility rate, this
may mean that populations could be nearly cut in half by 2100 (Ghosh, 2012). This could
cause severe economic problems especially when looked at from the perspective of the
elderly who will greatly outnumber the working. Social programs that rely heavily on
taxing the workers could be in danger and a production slowdown could be detrimental to
economic growth.
Pro-fertility policies in other OECD countries have been the target of many news
stories in the past decade. More and more countries are choosing to offer “baby bonuses,”
or a cash incentive, for parents having children. As fertility rates plummet around the
world, countries like France, Canada, Australia, Singapore, and Russia offer money to
mothers who have new children. While these policies may vary by size, family income,
and country, the idea is not new. For instance, Australia’s former Prime Minister Andrew
Fisher introduced a baby bonus of £5 per child in 1912 (Day, 2008). Because the “baby
bonus” has been introduced in countries to increase fertility rates, it is only necessary to
include it to tease out any effect on fertility rates that occur because of the bonus and not
because of increased maternity leave. The differences in these bonuses along with the
many stipulations that follow each policy make it difficult to delineate whether or not the
policy affects those targeted. However, in one regression I will introduce a binary
variable for countries that offer any type of “bonus” upon the arrival of a child. This does
not include tax breaks, tax credits, or any other policies that may make having a child
seem more attractive.
I am not concerned about missing values in my data, as the OECD data I am using
only refers to the weeks of paid or protected parental leave and the World Bank data
contains comparative numbers on fertility rates, GDP per capital and population. The
regressions I run on this data will take entity fixed effects into account, as the family and
work culture between the various ten countries may be different, resulting in differing
levels of fertility. I will also take GDP per capita into account because this may also have
an effect on fertility rates.
While other papers have been written addressing this issue, none have used panel
data that covers the amount of consecutive years and with the countries I plan to analyze
in my paper. In one study, researchers found that women in Austria were 4.9 percent
more likely to have an additional child within three years after a policy change that
increased the maximum duration of parental leave from one to two years (R. Lalive & R.
Lalive, 2005). In 2007, Germany expanded its parental benefits to not just cover low-
income families. The new policy allowed middle to upper class mothers to receive
benefits that depended on her pre-birth earnings. Researchers studying this policy found
that the change showed a significant effect on the increase of fertility (A. Raute, 2013).
Another policy analysis conducted by researchers in Australia found that reducing the
private costs associated with having children and increasing maternity leave exclusively
would not only increase fertility rates, but encourage women to return to the workforce
after their paid leave ends (L. Risse, 2006).
However, the paper most similar to what I would like to accomplish in this study,
“Demographic Consequences of Maternal Leave Programs in Industrialized Countries”
by Winegarden and Bracy (1995) looked at 17 OECD countries through four time
periods, 1959, 1969, 1979, and 1989. They found that extending maternity-leave
programs leads to reduced infant mortality rates, increased labor-force participation, and
an increase in birth rates. However, while the paid leave directly increased fertility rates,
maternity leave indirectly reduces fertility rates by increasing the woman’s labor supply,
thus leading to a net decrease in fertility rates. Not just this, but the results they found
related to paid maternity leave and fertility rates were statistically insignificant.
(Winegarden, C.R. & Bracy, P.M., 1995). Another paper by Gauthier and Hatzius (1997)
concluded that variations in maternity leave have no significant impact on fertility rates,
and it would be more useful to test this policy responsiveness between women of various
incomes, education levels, marital status, and labor force status (Gauthier, A.H. &
Hatzius, J, 1997).
The findings in these papers seem to show that as countries increase the weeks of
paid maternity leave for mothers, families will find that the opportunity cost of having a
child diminishes, thus having one or more children and increasing the fertility rates in the
respective countries. Furthermore, increasing paid maternity leave may increase fertility
rates in women that participate in the workforce, encouraging them to return upon
completion of their leave and increasing the female labor force participation. However,
for the women who do not participate in the work force, paid maternity leave will have
no impact on their childbearing decisions. Thus, a paid maternity leave may be better for
working women than a “baby bonus” or stipend, as these types of incentives may not
encourage workforce participation, while the stipend may provide incentives to
nonworking mothers.
Model
There are currently two common types of incentives being offered around the
world to families interested in having children. The first is some kind of paid parental
leave. The second is a family allowance or bonus offered to those who have children.
While this paper will mainly focus on paid maternity leave programs and their effect on
fertility rates, the “baby bonus” will be included in one model to tease out any effects it
may have on fertility rates that are unrelated to maternity leave. It should be noted that
many studies have found that cash benefits may have a more significant short term effect
on fertility rates. However, for the scope of this paper, the focus is on paid maternity
leave.
The first incentive, paid maternity leave, may directly increase fertility rates as
women are able to take leave of their work and still receive a percentage of their income.
However, because these women then return to the workforce, labor participation rates
increase which would in theory lower the fertility rates. As stated earlier, the second
incentive, baby bonuses, have been found by many studies to have a significant short
term effect on fertility rates. This may be due to the present-oriented nature of humans,
who highly discount the future, giving them a high discount rate and being more swayed
by money now rather than a slower, smaller, constant flow of money (e.g. paid maternity
leave and the assurance that a job is waiting for them after family leave).
Since the 1970’s women’s presence in the work force has increased in many
countries due to women’s rights and humanitarian reforms. This revolution has led to the
independence of women from men and challenged the traditional, societal role of women
at home. As more women began to work and depend less on their male counterparts,
divorce rates rose, fertility rates declined, and the work-life balance of having a job,
children, and a family were stretched thin (Quast, L., 2011). Paid maternity leave seems,
on the surface, a policy that would allow mothers and families to have it all. While
countries like the United States offer 12 weeks of protected leave for mothers, meaning
she has a right to take this time off from her job with the assurance of a comparable job
upon her return, paid leave offers some percentage of a woman’s wage while she is
tending to her newborn. This would, in theory, reduce the opportunity cost of having a
child and missing weeks of work all the while keeping women in the labor force.
Another argument that stems from the maternity leave debate is that paid leave
would allow a woman to care for her child longer, thus reducing the mortality rate of
infants. If a woman has more time to nurture her baby, the quality of her care is
improved as she is able to breastfeed for a longer period of time. The amount of income
she receives while taking a break from her job, while not as great as the amount she
would make by staying at work but greater than that she would receive without the
policy, would also allow her to increase her resources and improve the baby’s chance of
survival (Winegarden, C.R. & Bracy, P.M., 1995).
However, once a family with a working woman decides to have a child and the
woman returns to the workforce, what are the chances that she will leave again to have
another child? Without paid maternity leave, women may be more likely to drop out of
the workforce upon having a child. While having another child would result in some
financial obligation, this woman would not have to leave her job in order to do so. This
decision is quite different than the working woman, who may have to elect to put off a
promotion or professional opportunity to have one or more children.
Another problem concerning decreasing fertility rates is that many women with
professional careers choose not to have children or to put off having children all together.
A study published by Yale states that childlessness rates are strongly connected to
women’s educational levels (Chamie, J. & Mirken, B., 2012). For the working woman in
Switzerland, nearly 40% choose to be childless (Quast, L., 2011). Those who decide to
put off having children until they become older may struggle with fertility.
These social changes for women have resulted in substantial macroeconomic
gains. As countries chase gender equality, education rates rise, human capital is
enhanced, and productivity increases (Baptist, S., et al, 2010). While these changes are
good for families and result in better opportunities for the children born to them, the
macroeconomic gains associated with a higher educated female population may subside
as fertility rates plummet and the dying outnumber the born.
Does a higher amount of women in the workforce come at a fertility cost? The
hypothesis going forward is that as paid maternity leave programs increase, the fertility
rate will decrease. Because I suspect that women in the labor force and paid maternity
leave are positively correlated, I expect there to be no positive relationship between paid
maternity leave and increased fertility rates.
Data Description
The data I am using for the analysis of this question comes from multiple sources.
Much of it comes from the World Bank which provides a large amount of data to the
public. The infant mortality rate, GDP per capita, percent of population living in urban
centers relative to the total population, and the dependency rate all come from the World
Bank. This database provided the data for the years 1970 to 2013.
The second database I used was from the Organization for Economic Cooperation
and Development (OECD). From this database I retrieved the maximum length of paid
maternity leave for OECD countries.
The labor force participation rates for females comes from the U.S. Department of
Labor Bureau of Labor Statistics. This dataset contained the labor force participation
rates for ten countries beginning in 1960. Because this was the only data I could find
containing the labor force participation rates for females that covered such a wide length
of time, the decision was made to eliminate the countries which were not included on the
list and to focus instead on the ten countries with the data available. This decision, while
diminishing the amount of countries involved in the study, has enabled me to focus on the
long term effects of a paid maternity leave instead of using data for all OECD countries
beginning in the mid-1990s (when other data sets were available)
Descriptive statistics and a description of the variables used in my dataset are
summarized in Table 1. Using 440 observations from 10 countries over a period of 43
years, the average amount of paid maternity leave given to a woman is 14.7 weeks,
although some countries (the US included) do not offer paid maternity leave and others
(the United Kingdom)give up to a year of paid leave. This table also shows the wide
variation in country’s labor force participation rates, dependency rates, percent of the
population living in urban centers, and the change in infant mortality rates.
A list of the countries used in this analysis are located in Table 2. As previously
stated, these countries were chosen simply based on the available data for each. While
more observed countries would be preferable for this analysis, unfortunately much of this
data was missing.
Table 1. Description of Variables
Variable Description
m_weeks Number of weeks of paid leave available to mothers
f_rate Fertility rate
labfor Percentage of women participating in the labor force
urb Percentage of population living in an urban center
dep Dependency rate. Population age 65+ relative to population aged 15-64
imr Infant mortality rate (deaths per 1000 live births)
gdp_cap Per capita GDP at 2005 prices and exchange rates (US $)
lngdp_cap Natural log of gdp_cap
Table 2. Descriptive Statistics
Variable Obs. Mean Std. Dev. Min. Max.
m_weeks 440 14.7 11.73 0 52
f_rate 440 1.74 0.28 1.19 2.95
labfor 440 49 8.49 25.6 62.7
urb 440 77.05 6.44 61.66 92.49
dep 440 21.27 4.97 10.21 40.37
imr 440 7.97 4.62 2.1 29.7
gdp_cap 440 29544.59 7357.25 15155.83 46036.79
lngdp_cap 440 10.26 0.255 9.63 10.74
*This study uses data from Australia, Canada, France, Germany, Italy, Japan,
Netherlands, Sweden, United Kingdom, and the United States.
Empirical Model
In order to determine whether or not paid maternity leave or the presence of “baby
bonuses” affect fertility rates, I start with a panel regression of “f_rate” on “m_weeks.”
Using fertility rates as the dependent variable, I am able to add other independent
variables to the regression. However, because fertility rate may not be affected by policy
changes occurring in that same year, I conducted further regressions, testing different lag
effects. In total, I have four different methods of testing (lag year = 0, 1, 2, and 3) with
eight regressions for each of them. (See tables 2.1, 2.2, 2.3, 2.4)
I am regressing fertility rate on mandatory maternity leave with a vector of
country specific variables. Each of the equations is slightly different, some taking into
account country fixed effects, time fixed effects, both, or only certain years.
𝑌 = 𝐵0 + 𝐵1 𝑋1 + 𝐵1 𝑍1 + 𝑢 𝑖
As stated previously, to model the data so that fertility rates from a specific year
could be compared to the data from one year, two years, and three years prior, I also
regressed fertility on lagged regressor variables. This can be interpreted as: the fertility
rate of a country is affected by the government’s policy decisions made the previous year.
This similar thought process was used for the lag 2 and lag 3 year tables (Tables 2.3 and
2.4).
The results of the regressions can be seen in Tables 2.1, 2.2, 2.3, and 2.4 in the
Appendix.
These four separate regressions provide interesting details and allow me to
determine whether a change in policy has an immediate effect on fertility rates or whether
the effect does not occur for a couple of years. In all regressions, the final one (for years
1993 – 2013) seemed to have the least amount of omitted variable bias, with a substantial
R² value of at least 0.94. Furthermore, in almost every regression, mandated paid
maternity leave was not shown to have a significant effect on fertility rates. Similarly, we
see that baby bonuses never have a statistically significant effect on fertility rates in any
model.
The coefficient of determination rises as more variables are included into the
model, indicating that omitted variable bias is to blame in regression I, which emitted a
significant maternity leave coefficient. No matter which model is used (0, 1, 2, or 3 year
lag time) we see that the only variables that seem to be significant to the outcome of
fertility rates are the percent of women in the labor force, infant mortality rates, percent
of the population living in urban centers, and the dependency rate.
Discussion
Perhaps the most interesting result of this paper is that for the countries and years
selected, paid maternity leave seemed to have no significant effect on fertility rates. Even
as lag years were taken into account, the paid maternity leave coefficient is never
significant. However, contrary to the findings of Winegarden and Bracy (1995), we find
that in the set of regressions, as women’s participation in the labor force increases, so
does the fertility rate. I have some reservations about concluding that this is a long term
effect. My lag equations only take 1, 2, or 3 years of data into account, and long term
effects may be very different.
Another explanation for this finding is the general increase in women’s labor
force participation which may have occurred regardless of mandated maternity leave, as
it has in the United States. Similarly, an increase in education among women around the
world could have an effect on the labor force participation rate of women and the fertility
rate of women. Unfortunately, this data could not be found for all countries and years
included in this study. I believe that education rates among women may be a piece of
omitted variable bias that might give a biased analysis of this data.
We find that baby bonuses do not have any significant effect on fertility rates.
This may be for a few reasons. Baby bonuses are thought to have a short term effect on
fertility rates (Billari, 2009). Instead of increasing fertility rate, they speed up the births
of children that couples were already planning on having. Secondly, baby bonuses may
not be as attractive for a working woman as paid maternity leave, and thus do not have a
significant effect on labor force participation rates.
Some of the results discovered in these regressions which were not surprising
were that the lag models seemed to produce more significant coefficients than the model
with no lag, as it may take a year or more for the fertility rates of a country to be effected
by policies or changes in demographics. We also find that as the dependency rate
increases, fertility rates decrease. This is not very surprising, as individuals may delay or
forgo childrearing obligations if they are already caring for dependents.
One limitation in my data is the lack of variation in mandated maternity leave and
baby bonus payments over time. Many of the countries in my dataset did not change their
maternity leave policy for many years. Some countries have had baby bonuses in effect
since the 1970’s, while other do not have them at all, and finally even fewer have
implemented baby bonuses in the last couple of years. This makes the policy of paid
maternity leave and baby bonuses a very difficult one to analyze. Similarly, while some
countries may not offer baby bonuses, they may offer tax breaks or other incentives that
make having another child more attractive. For instance, many Japanese companies
pressured by politicians, have begun offering special deals to workers who have children
(Turner, D., 2007). While this may or may not be helpful in increasing fertility rates in
Japan, this could not be included in this macro model. Another difficulty in assessing the
benefit of baby bonuses is that many of these benefits are means-tested and may only
benefit women of a certain socioeconomic level. Other baby bonuses vary based on
whether or not the woman is having her first, second, or third child.
Another thing this study could not account for is the average amount of paid
maternity leave women receive. For instance, while paid maternity leave is not mandated
in the United States, many women receive paid maternity leave from the companies they
work for. This information may have skewed the data, as this was not taken into account.
Also, while some countries may offer a high percentage of a woman’s income to her
during her paid maternity leave, other countries do not. Because I did not have access to
the percentage of a woman’s wage offered to her during her paid maternity leave, I could
not account for these differences.
This data only uses information from ten countries. A shortage of
available data made it impractical to use any more countries. With more data, these
results may have been more significant or shown a larger effect of maternity leave or
baby bonuses on fertility rates. Using only these ten, developed countries may give a
biased analysis of the effect of paid maternity leave on fertility rates.
Conclusion
Unlike my initial hypothesis, it seems that a government mandated paid maternity
leave and “baby bonuses” have little to no significant effect on fertility rates. This could
be for a few different reasons. Firstly, the countries that have a mandated maternity leave
pay different percentages of the average weekly paycheck to new mothers. While one
country may pay new mothers very close to their average income, other countries are not
so generous. Secondly, the mandated maternity leave policies are not binding. So while
some mothers may take only the amount mandated by the government, others may
choose to go back to work earlier (due to the low percentage of paid wages) or stay out of
the workforce longer.
Another interesting piece of information that came up in this study is that while
some countries offer baby bonuses, these bonuses are typically means tested and thus
may only impact certain families with a specific socioeconomic status. In future studies,
it would be interesting to see how baby bonuses affect the fertility rates of families of
different incomes. Also, some companies in countries without baby bonuses offer
bonuses to their employees for new editions to their families. For example, under
pressure from the government, many Japanese companies are beginning to offer cash, cell
phones, and other incentives to new parents (Turner, D., 2007). Tracking these types of
incentives is difficult in a vast study such as the one I have done. Further, it is difficult to
decipher between what can be considered a baby bonus and what is a tax break in certain
situations. Some research shows that the success of baby bonuses increasing fertility rates
may also have to do with how much people trust their governments to follow through
with their promises, and that France has been the only country that has issued a
comprehensive policy that has increased fertility rates. However, this policy includes
mandated maternity leave, paid baby bonuses, and enormous tax breaks (Issues in Debate
Sociology, 2010). This paper did not look at tax breaks, although I believe that further
research may find that tax incentives are more attractive than bonuses and one time
payments.
In one study, researchers in Austria looked at a change in maternity leave policy
which shortened the duration of paid leave by 6 months and found that there was no
change in fertility rates (Lalive & Zweimuller, 2009), which may mean that maternity
leave is relatively inelastic. Even the paper by Winegarden that I modeled my research
after states that their final results showed that paid maternity leave had no statistically
significant effect on fertility rates.
In conclusion, this paper did not find any significant relationship between fertility
rates and paid maternity leave or baby bonuses. Perhaps future research that includes
socioeconomic variables such as income, education, and occupation may find a
correlation. Another interesting idea would be to look at the effect of certain tax policies
on fertility rates and perhaps focusing on one country.
Appendix A
Table 2.1 Regression Analysis of the Effect of Government Mandated Paid Maternity Leave on Fertility Rates
Dependent Variable: fertility rates (average births per woman)
Regressor 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8
Weeks of Paid Maternity Leave -0.00559
(0.001)*
-0.00689
(0.004)
-0.00026
(0.004)
-0.00259
(0.003)
-0.00019
(0.003)
-0.00252
(0.003)
0.00353
(0.005)
Percent of Women in Labor
Force
0.013654
(0.004)**
0.0088
(0.007)
0.0028
(0.003)
0.01734
(0.008)*
IMR 0.032769
(0.011)**
0.0367
(0.019)*
0.03819
(0.012)**
-0.0469
(0.038)
GDP per Capita 0.000003
(0.000)
0.00002
(0.000)
GDP per Capita (logarithm) -0.30597
(0.266)
0.10636
(.5654)
Population in Urban Areas 0.01073
(0.0040)*
0.0054
(0.004)
-0.00504
(0.005)
Dependency Rate -0.0270
(0.004)**
-0.02694
(0.004)**
-0.00357
(0.0104)
Baby Bonus (binary) 0.02239
(0.043)
-0.008
(0.036)
-0.00753
(0.054)
Years 1970-
2013
1970-
2013
1970-
2013
1970-
2013
1970-2013 1970-
2013
1970-
2013
1993-2013
Country Effects No Yes Yes No Yes Yes Yes Yes
Time Effects No No Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
R^2 0.0521 0.3902 0.7537 0.5496 0.8084 0.8026 0.8458 0.9435
The individual coefficient is statistically significant at the +10%, *5%, **1%, or ***0.1% significance level.
Appendix B
Table 2.2 Regression Analysis of the Effect of Government Mandated Paid Maternity Leave on Fertility Rates
Dependent Variable: fertility rates (average births per woman)
Regressor 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8
Weeks of Paid Maternity Leave
*Lagged 1 year
-0.00531
(0.001)**
-0.00457
(0.003)
-0.00054
(0.004)
-0.00241
(0.003)
-0.00112
(0.003)
-0.0008
(0.002)
0.00258
(0.006)
Percent of Women in Labor
Force *Lagged 1 year
0.014477
(0.004)**
0.01131
(0.007)
0.00699
(0.003)*
0.01459
(0.009)*
IMR
*Lagged 1 year
0.031886
(0.011)**
0.0361
(0.019)*
0.03851
(0.0118)**
-0.0634
(0.034)*
GDP per Capita
*Lagged 1 year
0.000003
(0.000)
0.00001
(0.000)
GDP per Capita (logarithm)
*Lagged 1 year
-0.31825
(0.293)
0.39024
(0.628)
Population in Urban Areas
*Lagged 1 year
0.01091
(0.003)**
0.00154
(0.004)
-0.00528
(0.005)
Dependency Rate
*Lagged 1 year
-0.02756
(0.005)**
-0.02433
(0.004)**
-0.00088
(0.0119)
Baby Bonus (binary)
*Lagged 1 year
0.02909
(0.039)
-0.0147
(0.0338)
-0.00982
(0.0501)
Years 1970-
2013
1970-
2013
1970-
2013
1970-
2013
1970-
2013
1970-
2013
1970-2013 1993-2013
Country Effects No Yes Yes No Yes Yes Yes Yes
Time Effects No No Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
R^2 0.0527 0.4345 0.7307 0.5168 0.7995 0.7856 0.8359 0.9443
The individual coefficient is statistically significant at the +10%, *5%, **1%, or ***0.1% significance level.
Appendix C
Table 2.3 Regression Analysis of the Effect of Government Mandated Paid Maternity Leave on Fertility Rates
Dependent Variable: fertility rates (average births per woman)
Regressor 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8
Weeks of Paid Maternity Leave
*Lagged 2 years
-0.00509
(0.001)**
-0.00255
(0.002)
-0.0011
(0.003)
-0.00228
(0.003)
-0.00223
(0.003)
-0.00061
(0.002)
0.0028
(0.006)
Percent of Women in Labor Force
*Lagged 2 years
0.015209
(0.004)**
0.01339
(0.007)*
0.01071
(0.003)**
0.01290
(0.008)+
IMR
*Lagged 2 years
0.03141
(0.011)**
0.0359
(0.019)*
0.03902
(0.012)**
-0.06965
(0.033)*
GDP per Capita
*Lagged 2 years
0.000003
(0.000)
0.00001
(0.000)
GDP per Capita (logarithm)
*Lagged 2 years
-0.34095
(0.329)
0.64855
(0.722)
Population in Urban Areas
*Lagged 2 years
0.01068
(0.003)**
-0.00239
(0.005)
-0.00562
(0.006)
Dependency Rate
*Lagged 2 years
-0.02757
(0.005)**
-0.02183
(0.005)**
-0.00319
(0.0131)
Baby Bonus (binary)
*Lagged 2 years
0.03322
(0.033)
-0.02447
(0.0291)
-0.00896
(0.045)
Years 1970-
2013
1970-
2013
1970-
2013
1970-
2013
1970-
2013
1970-
2013
1970-
2013
1993-2013
Country Effects No Yes Yes No Yes Yes Yes Yes
Time Effects No No Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
R^2 0.0549 0.4931 0.7065 0.4832 0.7941 0.7656 0.8323 0.9462
The individual coefficient is statistically significant at the +10%, *5%, **1%, or ***0.1% significance level.
Appendix D
Table 2.4 Regression Analysis of the Effect of Government Mandated Paid Maternity Leave on Fertility Rates
Dependent Variable: fertility rates (average births per woman)
Regressor 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8
Weeks of Paid Maternity Leave
*Lagged 3 years
-0.00504
(0.001)**
-0.00138
(0.002)
-0.0011
(0.003)
-0.00228
(0.003)
-0.00263
(0.003)
-0.00124
(0.002)
0.00451
(0.005)
Percent of Women in Labor Force
*Lagged 3 years
0.015862
(0.005)**
0.01476
(0.007)*
0.01328
(0.004)**
0.01125
(0.006)+
IMR
*Lagged 3 years
0.031205
(0.011)**
0.0354
(0.018)*
0.03912
(0.011)**
-0.07243
(0.0294)
*
GDP per Capita
*Lagged 3 years
0.000004
(0.000)
0.00001
(0.000)
GDP per Capita (logarithm)
*Lagged 3 years
-0.3292
(0.372)
0.84025
(0.774)
Population in Urban Areas
*Lagged 3 years
0.01064
(0.003)**
-0.00558
(0.006)
-0.00572
(0.006)
Dependency Rate
*Lagged 3 years
-0.02692
(0.006)**
-0.01977
(0.005)**
-0.00751
(0.013)
Baby Bonus (binary)
*Lagged 3 years
0.03901
(0.028)
-0.02902
(0.0282)
-0.00482
(0.041)
Years 1970-
2013
1970-
2013
1970-
2013
1970-2013 1970-
2013
1970-
2013
1970-2013 1993-
2013
Country Effects No Yes Yes No Yes Yes Yes Yes
Time Effects No No Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
R^2 0.0589 0.5474 0.6962 0.4696 0.7987 0.7555 0.8372 0.9488
The individual coefficient is statistically significant at the +10%, *5%, **1%, or ***0.1% significance level.
Bibliography
Chamie, J., and Mirkin, B. (2012, March 2). ”Childless by Choice,” Yale Global Online.
Retrieved from http://www.yaleglobal.yale.edu
Day, D. (2008). “Andrew Fisher: Prime minister of Australia,” HarperCollinsPublishers.
P. 258
Gauthier, A.H., and Hatzius, J. (1997). “Family Benefits and Fertility: An econometric
analysis,” Population Studies, 51, 295-306.
Ghosh, P. (2012). “Japan’s Demographic Doom: Tokyo’s Population will be cut in half
over next century,” International Business Times. Retrieved from
http://www.ibtimes.com/
Issues for Debate in Sociology: Selections from CQ Researcher. Los Angeles:
SAGE/Pine Forge, 2010.
Lalive, R and Lalive, R. (2005). “Does Parental Leave Affect Fertility and Return-to-
Work? Evidence from a ‘True Natural Experiment,’” no. 1614.
Lalive, R and Zweimuller, J. (2009).“How Does Parental Leave Affect Fertility and
Return to Work? Evidence from two natural experiements,” Quarterly Journal of
Economics, 124.3, 1363-1402.
Quast, L. (201, February 14). “Causes And Consequences of the Increasing Numbers of
Women in the Workforce,” Forbes.com. Retrieved from http://www.forbes.com
Raute, A. (2013).“Do Financial Incentives Affect Fertility – Evidence from a reform in
maternity leave benefits,”National Institute of Economic and Social Reform
Risse, L. (2006). “Does Maternity Leave Encourage Higher Birth Rates: An analysis of
the Australian labour force, “Aust. J. Labour Econ., vol. 9, no. 4, pp. 343-370.
Turner, D. (2007). ”Japan offers baby bonus to workers,” The Financial Times. Retrieved
from http://www.ft.com
Ward, J., Lee, B., Baptist, S., and Jackson, H. (2010, September). “Evidence for Action:
Gender Equality and Economic Growth,” Chatham House: Vivid Economics.
Winegarden, C.R. and Bracy, P.M. (1995). “Demographic Consequences of Maternal
Leave Programs in Industrialised Countries: Evidence from fixed-effects models,”
Southern Economic Journal, 61, 1020-1035.

More Related Content

What's hot

Segmentation
SegmentationSegmentation
Segmentation
Seana Copeland
 
Child Maintenance in the USA
Child Maintenance in the USAChild Maintenance in the USA
Child Support Debt and Father-Child Relationships
Child Support Debt and Father-Child RelationshipsChild Support Debt and Father-Child Relationships
Child Support Debt and Father-Child Relationships
Francesca Vescia (she/her)
 
Paid Family Leave 203 Term Paper
Paid Family Leave 203 Term PaperPaid Family Leave 203 Term Paper
Paid Family Leave 203 Term PaperCassandra Allen
 
Lost Opportunities for New Jersey's Children
Lost Opportunities for New Jersey's ChildrenLost Opportunities for New Jersey's Children
Lost Opportunities for New Jersey's Children
Jon Whiten
 
Kumsnus
KumsnusKumsnus
Kumsnus
kumsn
 
Doing Better for Families? The role of family policy in demographic change
Doing Better for Families?  The role of family policy in demographic changeDoing Better for Families?  The role of family policy in demographic change
Doing Better for Families? The role of family policy in demographic change
European Economic and Social Committee - SOC Section
 
Sec 2 Unit 3 population growth
Sec 2 Unit 3 population growthSec 2 Unit 3 population growth
Sec 2 Unit 3 population growth
critter33
 
The Sandwich Generation and Working Caregivers: How HR Can Guide Employees Ca...
The Sandwich Generation and Working Caregivers: How HR Can Guide Employees Ca...The Sandwich Generation and Working Caregivers: How HR Can Guide Employees Ca...
The Sandwich Generation and Working Caregivers: How HR Can Guide Employees Ca...
Casa Companion Homecare Solutions
 
Chapter 11 public assistance programs
Chapter 11 public assistance programsChapter 11 public assistance programs
Chapter 11 public assistance programs
ALMA HERNANDEZ, JD, LMSW
 
Teenage Motherhood and the Construction of the New Model Parent
Teenage Motherhood and the Construction of the New Model ParentTeenage Motherhood and the Construction of the New Model Parent
Teenage Motherhood and the Construction of the New Model Parent
ParentingCultureStudies
 
Parenting support in the context of violence prevention
Parenting support in the context of violence preventionParenting support in the context of violence prevention
Parenting support in the context of violence prevention
UNICEF Office of Research - Innocenti
 
Parenting support in the context of HIV
Parenting support in the context of HIVParenting support in the context of HIV
Parenting support in the context of HIV
UNICEF Office of Research - Innocenti
 
Gendered Roles in Parenting and Family Support in Ethiopia
Gendered Roles in Parenting and Family Support in EthiopiaGendered Roles in Parenting and Family Support in Ethiopia
Gendered Roles in Parenting and Family Support in Ethiopia
UNICEF Office of Research - Innocenti
 
Strong Support for Paid Family Leave
Strong Support for Paid Family LeaveStrong Support for Paid Family Leave
Strong Support for Paid Family Leave
Community Service Society of New York
 
Exploring the Landscape
Exploring the LandscapeExploring the Landscape
Exploring the Landscape
Mark Holmgren Consulting
 

What's hot (20)

Segmentation
SegmentationSegmentation
Segmentation
 
Child Maintenance in the USA
Child Maintenance in the USAChild Maintenance in the USA
Child Maintenance in the USA
 
Child Support Debt and Father-Child Relationships
Child Support Debt and Father-Child RelationshipsChild Support Debt and Father-Child Relationships
Child Support Debt and Father-Child Relationships
 
Paid Family Leave 203 Term Paper
Paid Family Leave 203 Term PaperPaid Family Leave 203 Term Paper
Paid Family Leave 203 Term Paper
 
Lost Opportunities for New Jersey's Children
Lost Opportunities for New Jersey's ChildrenLost Opportunities for New Jersey's Children
Lost Opportunities for New Jersey's Children
 
Kumsnus
KumsnusKumsnus
Kumsnus
 
Doing Better for Families? The role of family policy in demographic change
Doing Better for Families?  The role of family policy in demographic changeDoing Better for Families?  The role of family policy in demographic change
Doing Better for Families? The role of family policy in demographic change
 
Sec 2 Unit 3 population growth
Sec 2 Unit 3 population growthSec 2 Unit 3 population growth
Sec 2 Unit 3 population growth
 
The Sandwich Generation and Working Caregivers: How HR Can Guide Employees Ca...
The Sandwich Generation and Working Caregivers: How HR Can Guide Employees Ca...The Sandwich Generation and Working Caregivers: How HR Can Guide Employees Ca...
The Sandwich Generation and Working Caregivers: How HR Can Guide Employees Ca...
 
Chapter 11 public assistance programs
Chapter 11 public assistance programsChapter 11 public assistance programs
Chapter 11 public assistance programs
 
Teenage Motherhood and the Construction of the New Model Parent
Teenage Motherhood and the Construction of the New Model ParentTeenage Motherhood and the Construction of the New Model Parent
Teenage Motherhood and the Construction of the New Model Parent
 
Amst1410 final research paper
Amst1410 final research paperAmst1410 final research paper
Amst1410 final research paper
 
Parenting support in the context of violence prevention
Parenting support in the context of violence preventionParenting support in the context of violence prevention
Parenting support in the context of violence prevention
 
Capstone Final Paper
Capstone Final PaperCapstone Final Paper
Capstone Final Paper
 
ChildObesityNJ2015
ChildObesityNJ2015ChildObesityNJ2015
ChildObesityNJ2015
 
Keynote
KeynoteKeynote
Keynote
 
Parenting support in the context of HIV
Parenting support in the context of HIVParenting support in the context of HIV
Parenting support in the context of HIV
 
Gendered Roles in Parenting and Family Support in Ethiopia
Gendered Roles in Parenting and Family Support in EthiopiaGendered Roles in Parenting and Family Support in Ethiopia
Gendered Roles in Parenting and Family Support in Ethiopia
 
Strong Support for Paid Family Leave
Strong Support for Paid Family LeaveStrong Support for Paid Family Leave
Strong Support for Paid Family Leave
 
Exploring the Landscape
Exploring the LandscapeExploring the Landscape
Exploring the Landscape
 

Similar to Maternity Leave.Baker (1)

Paper Revised for Final
Paper Revised for FinalPaper Revised for Final
Paper Revised for FinalLondon Graves
 
33.pdf
33.pdf33.pdf
Canadian Journal of Economics Revue canadienne d’économique.docx
Canadian Journal of Economics  Revue canadienne d’économique.docxCanadian Journal of Economics  Revue canadienne d’économique.docx
Canadian Journal of Economics Revue canadienne d’économique.docx
dewhirstichabod
 
Parents employment and children welbeing
Parents employment and children welbeingParents employment and children welbeing
Parents employment and children welbeing
opondocarol
 
Policies to Assist Parents with Young ChildrenVO L . 2 1 .docx
Policies to Assist Parents with Young ChildrenVO L .  2 1 .docxPolicies to Assist Parents with Young ChildrenVO L .  2 1 .docx
Policies to Assist Parents with Young ChildrenVO L . 2 1 .docx
LeilaniPoolsy
 
MSc Extended Essay 2015
MSc Extended Essay 2015MSc Extended Essay 2015
MSc Extended Essay 2015Radhika Wadhwa
 
Reproductive Health and Economic Development: What Connections Should We Focu...
Reproductive Health and Economic Development: What Connections Should We Focu...Reproductive Health and Economic Development: What Connections Should We Focu...
Reproductive Health and Economic Development: What Connections Should We Focu...
The Population and Poverty Research Network
 
The rate of fertility in the United States
The rate of fertility in the United StatesThe rate of fertility in the United States
The rate of fertility in the United States
Danon Real Estate
 
Statistical-Learning-Project-Combined-1
Statistical-Learning-Project-Combined-1Statistical-Learning-Project-Combined-1
Statistical-Learning-Project-Combined-1Vivek-John Martins
 
Kearney levine-trends-nov2013-new nber
Kearney levine-trends-nov2013-new nberKearney levine-trends-nov2013-new nber
Kearney levine-trends-nov2013-new nberharamaya university
 
LloydAmanda.RevisedDraft
LloydAmanda.RevisedDraftLloydAmanda.RevisedDraft
LloydAmanda.RevisedDraftAmanda Lloyd
 
Expanding access-to-universal-childcare-effects-on
Expanding access-to-universal-childcare-effects-onExpanding access-to-universal-childcare-effects-on
Expanding access-to-universal-childcare-effects-on
Paperjam_redaction
 
ABSTRACT OF THE THESIS.docx
ABSTRACT OF THE THESIS.docxABSTRACT OF THE THESIS.docx
ABSTRACT OF THE THESIS.docx
lhye park
 
Taxing Families: The Impact of Child-related Transfers on Maternal Labor Supply
Taxing Families: The Impact of Child-related Transfers on Maternal Labor SupplyTaxing Families: The Impact of Child-related Transfers on Maternal Labor Supply
Taxing Families: The Impact of Child-related Transfers on Maternal Labor Supply
Stockholm Institute of Transition Economics
 
Measuring care gender, empowerment and the care economy
Measuring care gender, empowerment and the care economyMeasuring care gender, empowerment and the care economy
Measuring care gender, empowerment and the care economyDr Lendy Spires
 

Similar to Maternity Leave.Baker (1) (16)

Paper Revised for Final
Paper Revised for FinalPaper Revised for Final
Paper Revised for Final
 
33.pdf
33.pdf33.pdf
33.pdf
 
Canadian Journal of Economics Revue canadienne d’économique.docx
Canadian Journal of Economics  Revue canadienne d’économique.docxCanadian Journal of Economics  Revue canadienne d’économique.docx
Canadian Journal of Economics Revue canadienne d’économique.docx
 
Parents employment and children welbeing
Parents employment and children welbeingParents employment and children welbeing
Parents employment and children welbeing
 
Policies to Assist Parents with Young ChildrenVO L . 2 1 .docx
Policies to Assist Parents with Young ChildrenVO L .  2 1 .docxPolicies to Assist Parents with Young ChildrenVO L .  2 1 .docx
Policies to Assist Parents with Young ChildrenVO L . 2 1 .docx
 
MSc Extended Essay 2015
MSc Extended Essay 2015MSc Extended Essay 2015
MSc Extended Essay 2015
 
Reproductive Health and Economic Development: What Connections Should We Focu...
Reproductive Health and Economic Development: What Connections Should We Focu...Reproductive Health and Economic Development: What Connections Should We Focu...
Reproductive Health and Economic Development: What Connections Should We Focu...
 
The rate of fertility in the United States
The rate of fertility in the United StatesThe rate of fertility in the United States
The rate of fertility in the United States
 
Statistical-Learning-Project-Combined-1
Statistical-Learning-Project-Combined-1Statistical-Learning-Project-Combined-1
Statistical-Learning-Project-Combined-1
 
Kearney levine-trends-nov2013-new nber
Kearney levine-trends-nov2013-new nberKearney levine-trends-nov2013-new nber
Kearney levine-trends-nov2013-new nber
 
LloydAmanda.RevisedDraft
LloydAmanda.RevisedDraftLloydAmanda.RevisedDraft
LloydAmanda.RevisedDraft
 
Expanding access-to-universal-childcare-effects-on
Expanding access-to-universal-childcare-effects-onExpanding access-to-universal-childcare-effects-on
Expanding access-to-universal-childcare-effects-on
 
ABSTRACT OF THE THESIS.docx
ABSTRACT OF THE THESIS.docxABSTRACT OF THE THESIS.docx
ABSTRACT OF THE THESIS.docx
 
Complete Grant
Complete GrantComplete Grant
Complete Grant
 
Taxing Families: The Impact of Child-related Transfers on Maternal Labor Supply
Taxing Families: The Impact of Child-related Transfers on Maternal Labor SupplyTaxing Families: The Impact of Child-related Transfers on Maternal Labor Supply
Taxing Families: The Impact of Child-related Transfers on Maternal Labor Supply
 
Measuring care gender, empowerment and the care economy
Measuring care gender, empowerment and the care economyMeasuring care gender, empowerment and the care economy
Measuring care gender, empowerment and the care economy
 

Maternity Leave.Baker (1)

  • 1. Maternity Leave and Fertility Rates Jessica Baker University of Alaska Anchorage Seminar in Economic Research Professor Lance Howe December 10, 2015
  • 2. Abstract The aim of this paper is to determine the effect of mandated paid maternity leave on fertility rates in ten OECD countries from 1970 to 2012. The regression analysis using panel data for the ten countries seemed to indicate that a mandated paid maternity leave program has no statistically significant effect on fertility rates when controlled for time fixed effects and country fixed effects. Introduction While many American companies have made headlines in the last few years for offering extensive family leave packages, the United States is one of the only countries in the Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development (OECD) that does not require firms to offer paid maternity leave. Though the Family and Medical Leave Act of 1993 requires employers to keep a mother’s job open for 12 weeks while she is on maternity leave, many families may use their accrued paid leave or dig into their savings in order to make ends meet. This stress might result in many families postponing children or having fewer children than they would otherwise as the opportunity cost of having an additional child may be more than they are willing to incur. However, as other developed countries increase paid leave for both new mothers and fathers, the fertility rates in most advanced countries continue to fall. It is the objective of this paper to investigate the effect of the mandated policy of paid maternity leave on fertility rates in OECD countries. My paper will use OECD data from 1970 to 2012 on child-related leave from ten countries combined with data from the World Bank on fertility rates, GDP per capita,
  • 3. population, infant mortality rates, percent of those living in urban centers, and labor-force participation rates. The labor-force participation rates are important to include, as the amount of women in the labor force may explain dwindling fertility rates or may reflect a change in maternity leave policy. Many people assume that a falling fertility rate may be a good thing. For some countries, like Japan with a seriously declining fertility rate, this may mean that populations could be nearly cut in half by 2100 (Ghosh, 2012). This could cause severe economic problems especially when looked at from the perspective of the elderly who will greatly outnumber the working. Social programs that rely heavily on taxing the workers could be in danger and a production slowdown could be detrimental to economic growth. Pro-fertility policies in other OECD countries have been the target of many news stories in the past decade. More and more countries are choosing to offer “baby bonuses,” or a cash incentive, for parents having children. As fertility rates plummet around the world, countries like France, Canada, Australia, Singapore, and Russia offer money to mothers who have new children. While these policies may vary by size, family income, and country, the idea is not new. For instance, Australia’s former Prime Minister Andrew Fisher introduced a baby bonus of £5 per child in 1912 (Day, 2008). Because the “baby bonus” has been introduced in countries to increase fertility rates, it is only necessary to include it to tease out any effect on fertility rates that occur because of the bonus and not because of increased maternity leave. The differences in these bonuses along with the many stipulations that follow each policy make it difficult to delineate whether or not the policy affects those targeted. However, in one regression I will introduce a binary variable for countries that offer any type of “bonus” upon the arrival of a child. This does
  • 4. not include tax breaks, tax credits, or any other policies that may make having a child seem more attractive. I am not concerned about missing values in my data, as the OECD data I am using only refers to the weeks of paid or protected parental leave and the World Bank data contains comparative numbers on fertility rates, GDP per capital and population. The regressions I run on this data will take entity fixed effects into account, as the family and work culture between the various ten countries may be different, resulting in differing levels of fertility. I will also take GDP per capita into account because this may also have an effect on fertility rates. While other papers have been written addressing this issue, none have used panel data that covers the amount of consecutive years and with the countries I plan to analyze in my paper. In one study, researchers found that women in Austria were 4.9 percent more likely to have an additional child within three years after a policy change that increased the maximum duration of parental leave from one to two years (R. Lalive & R. Lalive, 2005). In 2007, Germany expanded its parental benefits to not just cover low- income families. The new policy allowed middle to upper class mothers to receive benefits that depended on her pre-birth earnings. Researchers studying this policy found that the change showed a significant effect on the increase of fertility (A. Raute, 2013). Another policy analysis conducted by researchers in Australia found that reducing the private costs associated with having children and increasing maternity leave exclusively would not only increase fertility rates, but encourage women to return to the workforce after their paid leave ends (L. Risse, 2006).
  • 5. However, the paper most similar to what I would like to accomplish in this study, “Demographic Consequences of Maternal Leave Programs in Industrialized Countries” by Winegarden and Bracy (1995) looked at 17 OECD countries through four time periods, 1959, 1969, 1979, and 1989. They found that extending maternity-leave programs leads to reduced infant mortality rates, increased labor-force participation, and an increase in birth rates. However, while the paid leave directly increased fertility rates, maternity leave indirectly reduces fertility rates by increasing the woman’s labor supply, thus leading to a net decrease in fertility rates. Not just this, but the results they found related to paid maternity leave and fertility rates were statistically insignificant. (Winegarden, C.R. & Bracy, P.M., 1995). Another paper by Gauthier and Hatzius (1997) concluded that variations in maternity leave have no significant impact on fertility rates, and it would be more useful to test this policy responsiveness between women of various incomes, education levels, marital status, and labor force status (Gauthier, A.H. & Hatzius, J, 1997). The findings in these papers seem to show that as countries increase the weeks of paid maternity leave for mothers, families will find that the opportunity cost of having a child diminishes, thus having one or more children and increasing the fertility rates in the respective countries. Furthermore, increasing paid maternity leave may increase fertility rates in women that participate in the workforce, encouraging them to return upon completion of their leave and increasing the female labor force participation. However, for the women who do not participate in the work force, paid maternity leave will have no impact on their childbearing decisions. Thus, a paid maternity leave may be better for working women than a “baby bonus” or stipend, as these types of incentives may not
  • 6. encourage workforce participation, while the stipend may provide incentives to nonworking mothers. Model There are currently two common types of incentives being offered around the world to families interested in having children. The first is some kind of paid parental leave. The second is a family allowance or bonus offered to those who have children. While this paper will mainly focus on paid maternity leave programs and their effect on fertility rates, the “baby bonus” will be included in one model to tease out any effects it may have on fertility rates that are unrelated to maternity leave. It should be noted that many studies have found that cash benefits may have a more significant short term effect on fertility rates. However, for the scope of this paper, the focus is on paid maternity leave. The first incentive, paid maternity leave, may directly increase fertility rates as women are able to take leave of their work and still receive a percentage of their income. However, because these women then return to the workforce, labor participation rates increase which would in theory lower the fertility rates. As stated earlier, the second incentive, baby bonuses, have been found by many studies to have a significant short term effect on fertility rates. This may be due to the present-oriented nature of humans, who highly discount the future, giving them a high discount rate and being more swayed by money now rather than a slower, smaller, constant flow of money (e.g. paid maternity leave and the assurance that a job is waiting for them after family leave).
  • 7. Since the 1970’s women’s presence in the work force has increased in many countries due to women’s rights and humanitarian reforms. This revolution has led to the independence of women from men and challenged the traditional, societal role of women at home. As more women began to work and depend less on their male counterparts, divorce rates rose, fertility rates declined, and the work-life balance of having a job, children, and a family were stretched thin (Quast, L., 2011). Paid maternity leave seems, on the surface, a policy that would allow mothers and families to have it all. While countries like the United States offer 12 weeks of protected leave for mothers, meaning she has a right to take this time off from her job with the assurance of a comparable job upon her return, paid leave offers some percentage of a woman’s wage while she is tending to her newborn. This would, in theory, reduce the opportunity cost of having a child and missing weeks of work all the while keeping women in the labor force. Another argument that stems from the maternity leave debate is that paid leave would allow a woman to care for her child longer, thus reducing the mortality rate of infants. If a woman has more time to nurture her baby, the quality of her care is improved as she is able to breastfeed for a longer period of time. The amount of income she receives while taking a break from her job, while not as great as the amount she would make by staying at work but greater than that she would receive without the policy, would also allow her to increase her resources and improve the baby’s chance of survival (Winegarden, C.R. & Bracy, P.M., 1995). However, once a family with a working woman decides to have a child and the woman returns to the workforce, what are the chances that she will leave again to have another child? Without paid maternity leave, women may be more likely to drop out of
  • 8. the workforce upon having a child. While having another child would result in some financial obligation, this woman would not have to leave her job in order to do so. This decision is quite different than the working woman, who may have to elect to put off a promotion or professional opportunity to have one or more children. Another problem concerning decreasing fertility rates is that many women with professional careers choose not to have children or to put off having children all together. A study published by Yale states that childlessness rates are strongly connected to women’s educational levels (Chamie, J. & Mirken, B., 2012). For the working woman in Switzerland, nearly 40% choose to be childless (Quast, L., 2011). Those who decide to put off having children until they become older may struggle with fertility. These social changes for women have resulted in substantial macroeconomic gains. As countries chase gender equality, education rates rise, human capital is enhanced, and productivity increases (Baptist, S., et al, 2010). While these changes are good for families and result in better opportunities for the children born to them, the macroeconomic gains associated with a higher educated female population may subside as fertility rates plummet and the dying outnumber the born. Does a higher amount of women in the workforce come at a fertility cost? The hypothesis going forward is that as paid maternity leave programs increase, the fertility rate will decrease. Because I suspect that women in the labor force and paid maternity leave are positively correlated, I expect there to be no positive relationship between paid maternity leave and increased fertility rates.
  • 9. Data Description The data I am using for the analysis of this question comes from multiple sources. Much of it comes from the World Bank which provides a large amount of data to the public. The infant mortality rate, GDP per capita, percent of population living in urban centers relative to the total population, and the dependency rate all come from the World Bank. This database provided the data for the years 1970 to 2013. The second database I used was from the Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development (OECD). From this database I retrieved the maximum length of paid maternity leave for OECD countries. The labor force participation rates for females comes from the U.S. Department of Labor Bureau of Labor Statistics. This dataset contained the labor force participation rates for ten countries beginning in 1960. Because this was the only data I could find containing the labor force participation rates for females that covered such a wide length of time, the decision was made to eliminate the countries which were not included on the list and to focus instead on the ten countries with the data available. This decision, while diminishing the amount of countries involved in the study, has enabled me to focus on the long term effects of a paid maternity leave instead of using data for all OECD countries beginning in the mid-1990s (when other data sets were available) Descriptive statistics and a description of the variables used in my dataset are summarized in Table 1. Using 440 observations from 10 countries over a period of 43 years, the average amount of paid maternity leave given to a woman is 14.7 weeks, although some countries (the US included) do not offer paid maternity leave and others (the United Kingdom)give up to a year of paid leave. This table also shows the wide
  • 10. variation in country’s labor force participation rates, dependency rates, percent of the population living in urban centers, and the change in infant mortality rates. A list of the countries used in this analysis are located in Table 2. As previously stated, these countries were chosen simply based on the available data for each. While more observed countries would be preferable for this analysis, unfortunately much of this data was missing. Table 1. Description of Variables Variable Description m_weeks Number of weeks of paid leave available to mothers f_rate Fertility rate labfor Percentage of women participating in the labor force urb Percentage of population living in an urban center dep Dependency rate. Population age 65+ relative to population aged 15-64 imr Infant mortality rate (deaths per 1000 live births) gdp_cap Per capita GDP at 2005 prices and exchange rates (US $) lngdp_cap Natural log of gdp_cap Table 2. Descriptive Statistics Variable Obs. Mean Std. Dev. Min. Max. m_weeks 440 14.7 11.73 0 52 f_rate 440 1.74 0.28 1.19 2.95 labfor 440 49 8.49 25.6 62.7 urb 440 77.05 6.44 61.66 92.49 dep 440 21.27 4.97 10.21 40.37 imr 440 7.97 4.62 2.1 29.7 gdp_cap 440 29544.59 7357.25 15155.83 46036.79 lngdp_cap 440 10.26 0.255 9.63 10.74 *This study uses data from Australia, Canada, France, Germany, Italy, Japan, Netherlands, Sweden, United Kingdom, and the United States. Empirical Model In order to determine whether or not paid maternity leave or the presence of “baby bonuses” affect fertility rates, I start with a panel regression of “f_rate” on “m_weeks.”
  • 11. Using fertility rates as the dependent variable, I am able to add other independent variables to the regression. However, because fertility rate may not be affected by policy changes occurring in that same year, I conducted further regressions, testing different lag effects. In total, I have four different methods of testing (lag year = 0, 1, 2, and 3) with eight regressions for each of them. (See tables 2.1, 2.2, 2.3, 2.4) I am regressing fertility rate on mandatory maternity leave with a vector of country specific variables. Each of the equations is slightly different, some taking into account country fixed effects, time fixed effects, both, or only certain years. 𝑌 = 𝐵0 + 𝐵1 𝑋1 + 𝐵1 𝑍1 + 𝑢 𝑖 As stated previously, to model the data so that fertility rates from a specific year could be compared to the data from one year, two years, and three years prior, I also regressed fertility on lagged regressor variables. This can be interpreted as: the fertility rate of a country is affected by the government’s policy decisions made the previous year. This similar thought process was used for the lag 2 and lag 3 year tables (Tables 2.3 and 2.4). The results of the regressions can be seen in Tables 2.1, 2.2, 2.3, and 2.4 in the Appendix. These four separate regressions provide interesting details and allow me to determine whether a change in policy has an immediate effect on fertility rates or whether the effect does not occur for a couple of years. In all regressions, the final one (for years 1993 – 2013) seemed to have the least amount of omitted variable bias, with a substantial R² value of at least 0.94. Furthermore, in almost every regression, mandated paid maternity leave was not shown to have a significant effect on fertility rates. Similarly, we
  • 12. see that baby bonuses never have a statistically significant effect on fertility rates in any model. The coefficient of determination rises as more variables are included into the model, indicating that omitted variable bias is to blame in regression I, which emitted a significant maternity leave coefficient. No matter which model is used (0, 1, 2, or 3 year lag time) we see that the only variables that seem to be significant to the outcome of fertility rates are the percent of women in the labor force, infant mortality rates, percent of the population living in urban centers, and the dependency rate. Discussion Perhaps the most interesting result of this paper is that for the countries and years selected, paid maternity leave seemed to have no significant effect on fertility rates. Even as lag years were taken into account, the paid maternity leave coefficient is never significant. However, contrary to the findings of Winegarden and Bracy (1995), we find that in the set of regressions, as women’s participation in the labor force increases, so does the fertility rate. I have some reservations about concluding that this is a long term effect. My lag equations only take 1, 2, or 3 years of data into account, and long term effects may be very different. Another explanation for this finding is the general increase in women’s labor force participation which may have occurred regardless of mandated maternity leave, as it has in the United States. Similarly, an increase in education among women around the world could have an effect on the labor force participation rate of women and the fertility rate of women. Unfortunately, this data could not be found for all countries and years
  • 13. included in this study. I believe that education rates among women may be a piece of omitted variable bias that might give a biased analysis of this data. We find that baby bonuses do not have any significant effect on fertility rates. This may be for a few reasons. Baby bonuses are thought to have a short term effect on fertility rates (Billari, 2009). Instead of increasing fertility rate, they speed up the births of children that couples were already planning on having. Secondly, baby bonuses may not be as attractive for a working woman as paid maternity leave, and thus do not have a significant effect on labor force participation rates. Some of the results discovered in these regressions which were not surprising were that the lag models seemed to produce more significant coefficients than the model with no lag, as it may take a year or more for the fertility rates of a country to be effected by policies or changes in demographics. We also find that as the dependency rate increases, fertility rates decrease. This is not very surprising, as individuals may delay or forgo childrearing obligations if they are already caring for dependents. One limitation in my data is the lack of variation in mandated maternity leave and baby bonus payments over time. Many of the countries in my dataset did not change their maternity leave policy for many years. Some countries have had baby bonuses in effect since the 1970’s, while other do not have them at all, and finally even fewer have implemented baby bonuses in the last couple of years. This makes the policy of paid maternity leave and baby bonuses a very difficult one to analyze. Similarly, while some countries may not offer baby bonuses, they may offer tax breaks or other incentives that make having another child more attractive. For instance, many Japanese companies pressured by politicians, have begun offering special deals to workers who have children
  • 14. (Turner, D., 2007). While this may or may not be helpful in increasing fertility rates in Japan, this could not be included in this macro model. Another difficulty in assessing the benefit of baby bonuses is that many of these benefits are means-tested and may only benefit women of a certain socioeconomic level. Other baby bonuses vary based on whether or not the woman is having her first, second, or third child. Another thing this study could not account for is the average amount of paid maternity leave women receive. For instance, while paid maternity leave is not mandated in the United States, many women receive paid maternity leave from the companies they work for. This information may have skewed the data, as this was not taken into account. Also, while some countries may offer a high percentage of a woman’s income to her during her paid maternity leave, other countries do not. Because I did not have access to the percentage of a woman’s wage offered to her during her paid maternity leave, I could not account for these differences. This data only uses information from ten countries. A shortage of available data made it impractical to use any more countries. With more data, these results may have been more significant or shown a larger effect of maternity leave or baby bonuses on fertility rates. Using only these ten, developed countries may give a biased analysis of the effect of paid maternity leave on fertility rates. Conclusion Unlike my initial hypothesis, it seems that a government mandated paid maternity leave and “baby bonuses” have little to no significant effect on fertility rates. This could be for a few different reasons. Firstly, the countries that have a mandated maternity leave
  • 15. pay different percentages of the average weekly paycheck to new mothers. While one country may pay new mothers very close to their average income, other countries are not so generous. Secondly, the mandated maternity leave policies are not binding. So while some mothers may take only the amount mandated by the government, others may choose to go back to work earlier (due to the low percentage of paid wages) or stay out of the workforce longer. Another interesting piece of information that came up in this study is that while some countries offer baby bonuses, these bonuses are typically means tested and thus may only impact certain families with a specific socioeconomic status. In future studies, it would be interesting to see how baby bonuses affect the fertility rates of families of different incomes. Also, some companies in countries without baby bonuses offer bonuses to their employees for new editions to their families. For example, under pressure from the government, many Japanese companies are beginning to offer cash, cell phones, and other incentives to new parents (Turner, D., 2007). Tracking these types of incentives is difficult in a vast study such as the one I have done. Further, it is difficult to decipher between what can be considered a baby bonus and what is a tax break in certain situations. Some research shows that the success of baby bonuses increasing fertility rates may also have to do with how much people trust their governments to follow through with their promises, and that France has been the only country that has issued a comprehensive policy that has increased fertility rates. However, this policy includes mandated maternity leave, paid baby bonuses, and enormous tax breaks (Issues in Debate Sociology, 2010). This paper did not look at tax breaks, although I believe that further
  • 16. research may find that tax incentives are more attractive than bonuses and one time payments. In one study, researchers in Austria looked at a change in maternity leave policy which shortened the duration of paid leave by 6 months and found that there was no change in fertility rates (Lalive & Zweimuller, 2009), which may mean that maternity leave is relatively inelastic. Even the paper by Winegarden that I modeled my research after states that their final results showed that paid maternity leave had no statistically significant effect on fertility rates. In conclusion, this paper did not find any significant relationship between fertility rates and paid maternity leave or baby bonuses. Perhaps future research that includes socioeconomic variables such as income, education, and occupation may find a correlation. Another interesting idea would be to look at the effect of certain tax policies on fertility rates and perhaps focusing on one country.
  • 17. Appendix A Table 2.1 Regression Analysis of the Effect of Government Mandated Paid Maternity Leave on Fertility Rates Dependent Variable: fertility rates (average births per woman) Regressor 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 Weeks of Paid Maternity Leave -0.00559 (0.001)* -0.00689 (0.004) -0.00026 (0.004) -0.00259 (0.003) -0.00019 (0.003) -0.00252 (0.003) 0.00353 (0.005) Percent of Women in Labor Force 0.013654 (0.004)** 0.0088 (0.007) 0.0028 (0.003) 0.01734 (0.008)* IMR 0.032769 (0.011)** 0.0367 (0.019)* 0.03819 (0.012)** -0.0469 (0.038) GDP per Capita 0.000003 (0.000) 0.00002 (0.000) GDP per Capita (logarithm) -0.30597 (0.266) 0.10636 (.5654) Population in Urban Areas 0.01073 (0.0040)* 0.0054 (0.004) -0.00504 (0.005) Dependency Rate -0.0270 (0.004)** -0.02694 (0.004)** -0.00357 (0.0104) Baby Bonus (binary) 0.02239 (0.043) -0.008 (0.036) -0.00753 (0.054) Years 1970- 2013 1970- 2013 1970- 2013 1970- 2013 1970-2013 1970- 2013 1970- 2013 1993-2013 Country Effects No Yes Yes No Yes Yes Yes Yes Time Effects No No Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes R^2 0.0521 0.3902 0.7537 0.5496 0.8084 0.8026 0.8458 0.9435 The individual coefficient is statistically significant at the +10%, *5%, **1%, or ***0.1% significance level.
  • 18. Appendix B Table 2.2 Regression Analysis of the Effect of Government Mandated Paid Maternity Leave on Fertility Rates Dependent Variable: fertility rates (average births per woman) Regressor 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 Weeks of Paid Maternity Leave *Lagged 1 year -0.00531 (0.001)** -0.00457 (0.003) -0.00054 (0.004) -0.00241 (0.003) -0.00112 (0.003) -0.0008 (0.002) 0.00258 (0.006) Percent of Women in Labor Force *Lagged 1 year 0.014477 (0.004)** 0.01131 (0.007) 0.00699 (0.003)* 0.01459 (0.009)* IMR *Lagged 1 year 0.031886 (0.011)** 0.0361 (0.019)* 0.03851 (0.0118)** -0.0634 (0.034)* GDP per Capita *Lagged 1 year 0.000003 (0.000) 0.00001 (0.000) GDP per Capita (logarithm) *Lagged 1 year -0.31825 (0.293) 0.39024 (0.628) Population in Urban Areas *Lagged 1 year 0.01091 (0.003)** 0.00154 (0.004) -0.00528 (0.005) Dependency Rate *Lagged 1 year -0.02756 (0.005)** -0.02433 (0.004)** -0.00088 (0.0119) Baby Bonus (binary) *Lagged 1 year 0.02909 (0.039) -0.0147 (0.0338) -0.00982 (0.0501) Years 1970- 2013 1970- 2013 1970- 2013 1970- 2013 1970- 2013 1970- 2013 1970-2013 1993-2013 Country Effects No Yes Yes No Yes Yes Yes Yes Time Effects No No Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes R^2 0.0527 0.4345 0.7307 0.5168 0.7995 0.7856 0.8359 0.9443 The individual coefficient is statistically significant at the +10%, *5%, **1%, or ***0.1% significance level.
  • 19. Appendix C Table 2.3 Regression Analysis of the Effect of Government Mandated Paid Maternity Leave on Fertility Rates Dependent Variable: fertility rates (average births per woman) Regressor 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 Weeks of Paid Maternity Leave *Lagged 2 years -0.00509 (0.001)** -0.00255 (0.002) -0.0011 (0.003) -0.00228 (0.003) -0.00223 (0.003) -0.00061 (0.002) 0.0028 (0.006) Percent of Women in Labor Force *Lagged 2 years 0.015209 (0.004)** 0.01339 (0.007)* 0.01071 (0.003)** 0.01290 (0.008)+ IMR *Lagged 2 years 0.03141 (0.011)** 0.0359 (0.019)* 0.03902 (0.012)** -0.06965 (0.033)* GDP per Capita *Lagged 2 years 0.000003 (0.000) 0.00001 (0.000) GDP per Capita (logarithm) *Lagged 2 years -0.34095 (0.329) 0.64855 (0.722) Population in Urban Areas *Lagged 2 years 0.01068 (0.003)** -0.00239 (0.005) -0.00562 (0.006) Dependency Rate *Lagged 2 years -0.02757 (0.005)** -0.02183 (0.005)** -0.00319 (0.0131) Baby Bonus (binary) *Lagged 2 years 0.03322 (0.033) -0.02447 (0.0291) -0.00896 (0.045) Years 1970- 2013 1970- 2013 1970- 2013 1970- 2013 1970- 2013 1970- 2013 1970- 2013 1993-2013 Country Effects No Yes Yes No Yes Yes Yes Yes Time Effects No No Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes R^2 0.0549 0.4931 0.7065 0.4832 0.7941 0.7656 0.8323 0.9462 The individual coefficient is statistically significant at the +10%, *5%, **1%, or ***0.1% significance level.
  • 20. Appendix D Table 2.4 Regression Analysis of the Effect of Government Mandated Paid Maternity Leave on Fertility Rates Dependent Variable: fertility rates (average births per woman) Regressor 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 Weeks of Paid Maternity Leave *Lagged 3 years -0.00504 (0.001)** -0.00138 (0.002) -0.0011 (0.003) -0.00228 (0.003) -0.00263 (0.003) -0.00124 (0.002) 0.00451 (0.005) Percent of Women in Labor Force *Lagged 3 years 0.015862 (0.005)** 0.01476 (0.007)* 0.01328 (0.004)** 0.01125 (0.006)+ IMR *Lagged 3 years 0.031205 (0.011)** 0.0354 (0.018)* 0.03912 (0.011)** -0.07243 (0.0294) * GDP per Capita *Lagged 3 years 0.000004 (0.000) 0.00001 (0.000) GDP per Capita (logarithm) *Lagged 3 years -0.3292 (0.372) 0.84025 (0.774) Population in Urban Areas *Lagged 3 years 0.01064 (0.003)** -0.00558 (0.006) -0.00572 (0.006) Dependency Rate *Lagged 3 years -0.02692 (0.006)** -0.01977 (0.005)** -0.00751 (0.013) Baby Bonus (binary) *Lagged 3 years 0.03901 (0.028) -0.02902 (0.0282) -0.00482 (0.041) Years 1970- 2013 1970- 2013 1970- 2013 1970-2013 1970- 2013 1970- 2013 1970-2013 1993- 2013 Country Effects No Yes Yes No Yes Yes Yes Yes Time Effects No No Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes R^2 0.0589 0.5474 0.6962 0.4696 0.7987 0.7555 0.8372 0.9488 The individual coefficient is statistically significant at the +10%, *5%, **1%, or ***0.1% significance level.
  • 21. Bibliography Chamie, J., and Mirkin, B. (2012, March 2). ”Childless by Choice,” Yale Global Online. Retrieved from http://www.yaleglobal.yale.edu Day, D. (2008). “Andrew Fisher: Prime minister of Australia,” HarperCollinsPublishers. P. 258 Gauthier, A.H., and Hatzius, J. (1997). “Family Benefits and Fertility: An econometric analysis,” Population Studies, 51, 295-306. Ghosh, P. (2012). “Japan’s Demographic Doom: Tokyo’s Population will be cut in half over next century,” International Business Times. Retrieved from http://www.ibtimes.com/ Issues for Debate in Sociology: Selections from CQ Researcher. Los Angeles: SAGE/Pine Forge, 2010. Lalive, R and Lalive, R. (2005). “Does Parental Leave Affect Fertility and Return-to- Work? Evidence from a ‘True Natural Experiment,’” no. 1614. Lalive, R and Zweimuller, J. (2009).“How Does Parental Leave Affect Fertility and Return to Work? Evidence from two natural experiements,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, 124.3, 1363-1402. Quast, L. (201, February 14). “Causes And Consequences of the Increasing Numbers of Women in the Workforce,” Forbes.com. Retrieved from http://www.forbes.com Raute, A. (2013).“Do Financial Incentives Affect Fertility – Evidence from a reform in maternity leave benefits,”National Institute of Economic and Social Reform Risse, L. (2006). “Does Maternity Leave Encourage Higher Birth Rates: An analysis of the Australian labour force, “Aust. J. Labour Econ., vol. 9, no. 4, pp. 343-370. Turner, D. (2007). ”Japan offers baby bonus to workers,” The Financial Times. Retrieved from http://www.ft.com Ward, J., Lee, B., Baptist, S., and Jackson, H. (2010, September). “Evidence for Action: Gender Equality and Economic Growth,” Chatham House: Vivid Economics. Winegarden, C.R. and Bracy, P.M. (1995). “Demographic Consequences of Maternal Leave Programs in Industrialised Countries: Evidence from fixed-effects models,” Southern Economic Journal, 61, 1020-1035.