SlideShare a Scribd company logo
1 of 27
Download to read offline
Urban Studies, Vol. 37, No. 12, 2287– 2313, 2000
An Entrepreneurial City in Action: Hong Kong’s
Emerging Strategies in and for (Inter)Urban
Competition
Bob Jessop and Ngai-Ling Sum
[Paper Žrst received, September 1999; in Ž nal form, April 2000]
Summary. The paper applies a Schumpeterian analysis of entrepreneurial cities to Hong Kong.
It argues that the concept of entrepreneurship can be applied to cities as strategic actors,
identiŽ es various objects of urban entrepreneurship, and refers to the important role of
entrepreneurial discourses, narratives and self-images. Despite its laissez-faire reputation, Hong
Kong has a long history of urban entrepreneurship, but its strategies have been adapted to
changing circumstances—most recently with its key role in an emerging cross-border region
(Greater China) and its favourable insertion into the global economy. This has prompted a
debate over the most appropriate strategies for Hong Kong, notably regarding the respective
futures of manufacturing, services and the virtual economy. The concept of ‘glurbanisation’ as
one form of the more general phenomenon of ‘glocalisation’ is introduced to illuminate these
issues. The paper concludes by noting the increased importance of ‘Siliconisation’ as an
accumulation strategy in east Asia.
There is widespread interest among policy-
makers and observers alike in the en-
trepreneurial city. It is less obvious what
exactly being an entrepreneurial city in-
volves. To help resolve this conundrum, our
paper Ž rst provides a Schumpeterian analysis
of the entrepreneurial city and then illustrates
it with the Hong Kong case. We Ž rst offer a
three-part deŽ nition of the entrepreneurial
city in capitalist societies. This relates urban
entrepreneurship to changing forms of com-
petitiveness, changing strategies to promote
interurban competitiveness in both the econ-
omic and extra-economic Ž elds and en-
trepreneurial discourses, narratives and
self-images. Schumpeter identiŽ ed Ž ve ways
in which entrepreneurs innovate in normal
economic activities; our analysis identiŽ es
parallels in urban entrepreneurialism. We
then critically consider how far such an
analysis is valid given the differences be-
tween the types of actor involved and the
objects of their innovation—answering
afŽ rmatively in both respects and suggesting
the conditions in which cities can be de-
scribed as strategic actors with entrepreneu-
rial ambitions. This theoretical analysis is
further reŽ ned and justiŽ ed from recent de-
velopments in Hong Kong and east Asia.
Conventionally regarded as a paradigm case
of laissez-faire and ofŽ cially described in the
decades before 1997 as practising ‘positive
Bob Jessop is in the Department of Sociology, Lancaster University, Lancaster, LA1 4YL, UK. Fax: 01524 594256.
E-mail: b.jessop@lancaster.ac.uk. Ngai-Ling Sum is with the International Centre for Labour Studies, Williamson Building, University
of Manchester, Oxford Road, Manchester, M13 9PL, UK. E-mail: Ngai-Ling.Sum@man.ac.uk. The authors have have beneŽ ted from
discussions with Neil Brenner, Carolyn Cartier, Anne Haila, Gordon McLeod, Jamie Peck and Ngai Pun. The usual disclaimers apply.
0042-0980 Print/1360-063X On-line/00/122287-27 Ó 2000 The Editors of Urban Studies
DOI: 10.1080/0042098002 0002814
BOB JESSOP AND NGAI-LING SUM
2288
non-intervention’, Hong Kong actually has a
long history of urban entrepreneurship based
on public–private partnerships. But its strate-
gies have been modiŽ ed as the economic and
political environments have changed. Our
contribution is particularly concerned with
the recent period, when Hong Kong’s en-
trepreneurial city strategies have been devel-
oped against the background of an emerging
cross-border regional space (Greater China)
and its favourable insertion into the global
circuits of capital. In this context we intro-
duce the concept of ‘glurbanisation’ as one
form of the more general phenomenon of
‘glocalisation’ and show how it can be used
to illuminate current entrepreneurial city
strategies in east Asia.
Thus the second part of the paper de-
scribes how, between the 1970s and the early
1990s, Hong Kong responded in two ways to
the growing relocation of its local manufac-
turing activities to the mainland. It became
the key node in co-ordinating ‘sub-contract-
ing management’ for the ‘Greater China’
region; and, in addition, its increasingly in-
ternationalised Ž nancial and producer ser-
vices sectors expanded to Ž ll the gaps created
by the ‘hollowing-out’ of Hong Kong’s local
manufacturing base. Hong Kong’s continu-
ing rise from the mid 1980s onwards as a
regional Ž nancial centre provided ample
funds for further expansion by local property
capital. These structural shifts strengthened
the position of Ž nance and property capital in
the local power bloc. As property became an
increasingly important sphere of capital ac-
cumulation, industrial and commercial capi-
tals worried about the lack of high-tech
investment and the rising cost of all econ-
omic activities in Hong Kong. This was
re ected in the development of two major
alternative urban strategic orientations or-
ganised around the competing interests of
industry and producer services and con-
cerned in their different ways with problems
of interscalar articulation and chronotopic
governance. Mobilising support for, and pur-
suing, these strategies was complicated in the
mid 1990s by the primacy of political calcu-
lations around the transition (on this period,
see Sum, 1995). Moreover, shortly after the
1997 return of Hong Kong to the mainland,
the outbreak of the Asian crisis initially dis-
oriented and disrupted these strategies. When
the crisis stabilised in early 1999, however,
the competing visions took on a new life and
generated even more explicit and re exive
urban entrepreneurialism. In particular, since
urban economic growth is locked into a prop-
erty-related path, the government is now
seeking to build a new urban bloc.1
This
would consolidate real estate, commercial
and technological interests around new en-
trepreneurial projects such as a science park,
cyberport and Chinese-medicine port.2
Such
projects serve to unify different interests in
Hong Kong and are also mediating the
emergence of a global–regional–national
bloc of economic actors involved in infor-
mation and communication technologies and
services—in the case of the cyberport, for
example, these include Microsoft, Acer from
Taiwan and IT Ž rms from Hong Kong and
China. These entrepreneurial projects are by
no means unique to Hong Kong and, indeed,
they are facing competition from similar
projects in Singapore, Kuala Lumpur and
Beijing.
1. What is an Entrepreneurial City?
It might be argued that entrepreneurial cities
have existed for centuries, if not millennia
and, in terms of institutional structures and
strategies supporting economic innovation,
this could well be true (see, for example,
Hall, 1998; Braudel, 1984; Jacobs, 1984;
Taylor, 1995). But this argument views cities
as engines of wealth creation regardless of
the speciŽ c form in which this occurs—and
so fails to capture what is novel about the
role of entrepreneurial cities in capital accu-
mulation. (On the distinction between wealth
and capital, see Postone, 1993). The litera-
ture on urban growth machines does combine
a focus on wealth creation with interest in the
dynamics of property capital and in this re-
gard has some similarities with our own ap-
proach. But urban growth machine studies
have been more concerned with local devel-
AN ENTREPRENEURIAL CITY IN ACTION 2289
opmental strategies and the political alliances
that support them than with issues of inter-
scalar articulation and they have also exam-
ined a restricted range of the entrepreneurial
strategies that we identify below. In addition,
our own approach highlights the importance
of entrepreneurial discourse and narratives
and is concerned with the periodisation of
strategies—something that is neglected in the
urban growth machine literature (for com-
mentaries on the latter, see Jonas and Wilson,
1999). In particular, we propose three
deŽ ning features of entrepreneurial cities:
—An entrepreneurial city pursues innovative
strategies intended to maintain or enhance
its economic competitiveness vis-à-vis
other cities and economic spaces.
—These strategies are real and re exive.
They are not ‘as if’ strategies, but are more
or less explicitly formulated and pursued
in an active, entrepreneurial fashion.
—The promoters of entrepreneurial cities
adopt an entrepreneurial discourse, narrate
their cities as entrepreneurial and market
them as entrepreneurial.
The Ž rst and second criteria distinguish cities
that happen for whatever reason(s) to per-
form well economically from those that are
entrepreneurial. For not all cities that per-
form well are entrepreneurial; and not all
entrepreneurial cities perform well. Adopting
the second criterion directs attention to the
conditions under which cities can be said to
act in a relatively uniŽ ed and strategic man-
ner and/or in which speciŽ c social forces are
able to deŽ ne the interests of the city and be
seen to act for and on behalf of the latter.
Only where explicit strategies are pursued
can we talk of an entrepreneurial city. The
third criterion is useful in distinguishing the
entrepreneurial city from non-entrepreneurial
urban regimes. Urban regimes and urban
blocs pursue many different kinds of econ-
omic, political and socio-cultural strategy—
for example, religious centre, dream factory,
imperial capital, modernist utopia, municipal
socialism or tourist centre (Hall, 1998).
Only some adopt an explicitly entrepreneu-
rial self-identity as well as an entrepreneurial
strategy.
Our approach to the Ž rst and second cri-
teria for identifying entrepreneurial cities is
in uenced by Schumpeter, an emblematic
thinker for contemporary capitalism, who
deŽ ned entrepreneurship as the creation of
opportunities for surplus proŽ t through ‘new
combinations’ or innovation (Schumpeter,
1934); and by Harvey, an arguably more
controversial thinker on post-modern capital-
ism, who has presented some in uential
ideas on the shift from urban managerialism
to urban entrepreneurialism (Harvey, 1989).
Their work is very useful in deŽ ning the
nature of entrepreneurial strategies oriented
to enhancing the competitiveness of cities
and regions.
Schumpeter listed several ways in which
innovation can occur:
(1) The introduction of a new good—that
is one with which consumers are not yet
familiar—or a new quality of a good. (2)
The introduction of a new method of pro-
duction, that is one not yet tested by ex-
perience in the branch of manufacture
concerned, which need by no means be
founded upon a discovery scientiŽ cally
new, and can also exist in a new way of
handling a commodity commercially. (3)
The opening of a new market, that is a
market into which the particular branch of
manufacture of the country in question has
not previously entered, whether or not this
market has existed before. (4) The con-
quest of a new source of supply of raw
materials or half-manufactured goods,
again irrespective of whether this source
already exists or whether it has Ž rst to be
created. (5) The carrying out of the new
organization of any industry, like the cre-
ation of a monopoly position (for example
through trustiŽ cation) or the breaking up
of a monopoly position (Lim, 1990,
p. 215; summarising Schumpeter, 1934,
pp. 129–135).
Schumpeter was concerned with entrepreneu-
rial innovation in the supply of commodities
by Ž rms as economic actors. One might ob-
BOB JESSOP AND NGAI-LING SUM
2290
ject that cities are not Ž rms and do not
produce commodities.3
But a Schumpeterian
interpretation of cities focuses on cities’
overall capacities to promote innovation in
urban form and also adopts a broader account
of competition that includes extra-economic
as well as economic factors. Thus cities can
be entrepreneurial not only in regard to com-
modities and Ž ctitious commodities, but also
in regard to economically relevant factors
that are not monetised and/or do not enter
directly into exchange relations. The chang-
ing forms of competition are especially im-
portant here because extra-economic factors
have become more central to economic com-
petitiveness (see Veltz, 1996).
In these terms, we can identify Ž ve analyt-
ically distinct (but perhaps empirically over-
lapping) Ž elds in which directly economic
and/or economically relevant innovation can
occur in relation to urban form and functions.
These Ž elds comprise:
(1) The introduction of new types of urban
place or space for producing, servicing,
working, consuming, living, etc. Recent
examples include technopoles, intelligent
cities, cross-border cities, multicultural
cities and cities organised around inte-
grated transport and sustainable develop-
ment.
(2) New methods of space or place pro-
duction to create location-speciŽ c advan-
tages for producing goods/services or
other urban activities. Recent examples
include the installation of new physical,
social and cybernetic infrastructures, the
promotion of scale and agglomeration
economies, regulatory undercutting or
creating new forms of labour market re-
lation.
(3) Opening new markets—whether by
place marketing speciŽ c cities in new
areas and/or modifying the spatial div-
ision of consumption through enhancing
the quality of life for residents, com-
muters or visitors (for example, culture,
entertainment, spectacles, new city-
scapes, gay quarters, gentriŽ cation).
(4) Finding new sources of supply to en-
hance competitive advantages. Examples
include new sources or patterns of immi-
gration, changing the cultural mix of cit-
ies, Ž nding new sources of funding from
the central state (or, in the EU, European
funds), attracting inward investment or
reskilling the workforce.
(5) ReŽ guring or redeŽ ning the urban hier-
archy and/or altering the place of a given
city within it. Examples include the de-
velopment of a world or global city pos-
ition, regional gateways, hubs,
cross-border regions and ‘virtual re-
gions’ based on interregional co-oper-
ation among non-contiguous spaces.
Each of these forms of activity can be seen as
innovative or entrepreneurial in the Schum-
peterian sense and each of their objects also
provides a possible basis for explicit urban
strategies. This does not mean, of course,
that each and every new place or space, new
method of space or place production, new
market, new source of supply or new urban
hierarchy results directly from successful re-
alisation of explicit entrepreneurial strate-
gies. This qualiŽ cation is required not only
because highly original innovations can soon
become routinised through ‘swarming’ ef-
fects (for example, science parks,
technopoles or waterfront regeneration re-
development schemes) but also because new
phenomena can emerge from the impersonal
play of the market mechanism rather than
explicitly formulated entrepreneurial or
managerial strategies. Indeed, whilst Ž rst
movers often introduce innovations in a more
spontaneous, less re ective way, it is follow-
ers who tend to be more explicitly en-
trepreneurial. An interesting example
relevant to our concerns below is the rise of
Silicon Valley as an innovative milieu com-
pared with attempts to replicate its success
elsewhere.
Regarding the second criterion, cities can
be deŽ ned as ‘entrepreneurial’ actors only if
they are meaningful units of competition and
able to pursue competitive strategies. Other-
wise they could at best be said to be re-
presenting or marketing themselves as such
AN ENTREPRENEURIAL CITY IN ACTION 2291
through entrepreneurial narratives and/or to
be serving as sites more or less favourable to
entrepreneurial initiatives emanating from
elsewhere. Nonetheless, Cox and Mair sug-
gest that
If people interpret localized social struc-
tures in explicitly territorial terms, come to
view their interests and identities as ‘lo-
cal’, and then act upon that view by mobi-
lizing locally deŽ ned organizations to
further their interests in a manner that
would not be possible were they to act
separately, then it seems eminently reason-
able to talk about ‘locality as agent’ (Cox
and Mair, 1991, p. 198).
These conditions would also apply (without
being sufŽ cient) to the mobilisation of di-
verse social forces and organisational capac-
ities around common entrepreneurial
projects. Key elements here would include:
the discursive constitution of economic
paradigms, identities and modes of calcu-
lation that justify claims about an ‘imagined
community of entrepreneurial interest’ and
its associated collective project, the nature
and competencies of the actors (not necess-
arily local or locally dependent) who are
mobilised behind the entrepreneurial strat-
egy, the interpersonal, organisational and (in-
ter)organisational mechanisms through
which such forces are mobilised and given
coherence, and the manner in which these
mechanisms are embedded in broader social
arrangements so that the capacities of the city
(or localised social structure) are in some
sense collective and thus irreducible to those
of individual actors resident or active therein.
In considering how entrepreneurial cities
can acquire coherence as collective social
forces, we might start with political struc-
tures and city politicians. In this context, for
example, Clarke and Gaile (1998, p. 13) note
that entrepreneurial strategies are more likely
in US cities with strong mayoral leadership
(and, for similar arguments about Europe,
see Harding, 1995; Parkinson and Harding,
1995; and Le Galès and Harding, 1998). The
roles of the Tung Chee-Hwa, the Chief
Executive of Hong Kong, or Goh Chok
Tong, Prime Minister of Singapore, provide
clear parallels to such mayoral leadership.
New Labour’s promotion of city mayors in
Britain, beginning in 2000 with London, also
represents a move in the direction of creating
conditions for more effective mobilisation
behind urban entrepreneurial projects. But
we must look beyond city dignitaries to a
wider range of actors who might be mo-
bilised behind a collective project and to the
institutional factors that might help to con-
solidate their support. Such actors can in-
clude branches of the local, central and,
where relevant, supranational state; quangos
and hived-off state agencies; political parties;
Ž rms; consultancies; trade associations and
chambers of commerce; employers’ organi-
sations; business roundtables; trades unions;
trades councils; citizens’ and community
groups; voluntary-sector organisations; pub-
lic–private partnerships; local educational
and religious institutions; social movements;
and diasporic communities. In this sense, the
capacity to pursue entrepreneurial strategies
and the sort of strategies that are likely to be
pursued will clearly depend on state institu-
tional and/or territorial structures as well as
on broader economic, political and socio-
cultural factors. More speciŽ cally, the solid-
ity of such projects will depend on their
interpersonal, interorganisational and institu-
tional embeddedness (hence the existence not
only of partnerships but networks of partner-
ships structured both horizontally and verti-
cally) as well as their feasibility in the light
of existing structural constraints and horizons
of action.
The ability to engage in collective action
is linked to capacities for re exion and self-
observation and the transformation of what
Lipietz calls ‘space-in-itself’ into ‘space-for-
itself’. This occurs through the development
of a ‘regional armature’ (or regional state
apparatus) organised around an urban or re-
gional bloc (Lipietz, 1985/1994). Indeed,
re exivity has become more important in
tandem with the emergence of new forms of
uncertainty and risk as market forces and the
extra-economic environment of economic ac-
tion become more turbulent, more in uenced
BOB JESSOP AND NGAI-LING SUM
2292
by the strategic calculation of other actors
and more open to in uence on a wide range
of spatial scales. These changes privilege
forms of urban organisation that enable econ-
omic actors to share risks and cope with
uncertainty through dense social and institu-
tional networks (Storper, 1997; Veltz, 1996).
This is why a well-established regional arma-
ture is useful. Moreover, because the dy-
namic competitive advantages that derive
from innovation are likely to be competed
away as other economic actors adopt them, it
is essential to sustain the economic and ex-
tra-economic capacities for ‘permanent inno-
vation’. This typically requires a degree of
(self-)re exivity that is absent in weakly
competitive entrepreneurial cities and/or
those that merely engage in boosterism or
city marketing.
The third criterion appears more straight-
forward. For it requires that the promoters of
entrepreneurial cities adopt an entrepreneu-
rial discourse, narrate their cities as en-
trepreneurial and market them as
entrepreneurial. This involves the articulation
of diverse economic, political and socio-
cultural narratives and complementary non-
narrative discourses to contextualise and
reinforce calls for entrepreneurial action.
These narratives often seek to give meaning
to current problems by construing them in
terms of past failures and future possibilities.
In the case of entrepreneurial cities, such
narratives typically refer to (actual or poten-
tial) losses of competitiveness and the imper-
atives and opportunities to restore it in one
way or another. This is typically deemed to
require decisive changes in the purposes, or-
ganisation and delivery of economic strate-
gies that are focused on the local, urban or
regional levels and infused with some kind of
entrepreneurial spirit. Such calls involve the
portrayal of the local, urban or regional econ-
omy as a distinctive object (of analysis, regu-
lation, governance, conquest and/or other
practices) with deŽ nite boundaries,4
econ-
omic and extra-economic conditions of exist-
ence, typical economic agents and
extra-economic stakeholders, and an overall
dynamic (see Barnes and Ledubur, 1991;
Daly, 1993). And they also seek to get social
forces on various scales (not just local actors)
to identity their interests with the promotion
of this (imagined) local, urban or regional
economy and the economic and extra-
economic conditions presented as necessary
to its future success. Where this strategy
involves explicit reference to entrepreneurial
narratives, strategies and self-identities, then
the third criterion for an entrepreneurial city
is also satisŽ ed.
It is worth noting here that the scope for
urban entrepreneurialism has grown in
tandem with the expansion of discourses
about competitiveness and potential means of
enhancing it. In particular, there has been a
shift from simple Ricardian concepts of com-
petitiveness, based on the relative abundance
and relative cost of different factors of pro-
duction, to a concern with complex forms of
structural or systemic competitiveness. These
involve not only socially embedded econ-
omic relations (as well as disembedded fac-
tors of production), but also extra-economic
phenomena, such as education, public–
private partnerships, industry–Ž nance rela-
tions, state forms, intellectual property
regimes, enterprise culture and so on (on
structural competitiveness, see Chesnais,
1986; on systemic competitiveness, Messner,
1996). We will illustrate these arguments
below (see also Jessop, 1997 and 1999).
2. Interscalar Strategies
Cities engage in different kinds of interscalar
strategy. Even if they do not act directly as
economic entrepreneurs producing commodi-
ties (for example, as sponsors of property-led
development, tourist spectacles, etc.), cities
may still promote an entrepreneurial environ-
ment on a range of scales that might help to
sustain local growth and make the best use of
any opportunities to promote entrepreneur-
ship and/or market their places/spaces. In this
regard, several strategies can be identiŽ ed.
These differ in at least three respects: their
respective concepts and discourses of com-
petitiveness, the spatial and scalar horizons
over which they are meant to operate and
AN ENTREPRENEURIAL CITY IN ACTION 2293
their association with different local contexts
and positions in prevailing urban hierarchies.
What they share is an important role for
urban or metropolitan authorities in their
overall framing and promulgation. In this
sense, for all the talk of the crisis of the state
(at whatever level), public authorities still
appear to have a major role in organising
entrepreneurial policies for the city (includ-
ing inner cities and metropolitan regions),
re ecting on them and narrating such poli-
cies in entrepreneurial terms.
A common neo-liberal strategy is con-
cerned to attract inward investment and/or to
retain extant investment through a Ricardian
cost-cutting and deregulatory strategy
(Leicht and Jenkins, 1994). This is associated
with a static comparative advantage approach
to competitiveness, an indifference to scalar
articulation and a weak rank in urban hier-
archies. A broadly similar but more neo-
statist strategy occurs where urban
authorities seek resources from higher tiers
of government and, perhaps, deploy these to
lever additional private investment. Overall,
these strategies involve weak forms of com-
petition that are unlikely to be sustainable in
the long term and they also pose an awkward
dilemma over the trade-off between main-
taining local autonomy and accepting re-
sources that come with restrictive strings
attached.
Another broad set of strategies, linked to
neo-corporatist and neo-statist as well as
neo-liberal approaches, involves pursuing
some form of structured coherence across
scales by building favourable linkages to the
wider economy. Such strategies are usually
based on a dynamic comparative advantage
approach to competitiveness—often linked in
turn to notions of structural and/or systemic
competitiveness (see above)—and a strong
concern with interscalar articulation. More-
over, depending on cities’ position in various
urban hierarchies or networks, they can cre-
ate weaker or stronger forms of competition.
In this regard, there are three possible strate-
gies (by no means mutually exclusive, let
alone exhaustive) that are linked to differ-
ences in the preferred form of scalar articula-
tion. The Ž rst option is to build horizontal
linkages on the same scale (for example,
cross-border regions, translocal alliances and
‘virtual regions’ linking non-contiguous
locales with shared or complementary inter-
ests—such as the European ‘Four Motors’
regions). These horizontal strategies often
build on common territorial interests and
identities and exploit complementary or joint
resources and capacities. Bodies on higher
tiers or scales may also promote them—
witness the case of the European Union. The
second option is to pursue structured comple-
mentarities based on a scalar division of
labour in an integrated, vertically nested set
of scales. This strategy typically involves
promoting economic development (on what-
ever scale) by exploiting growth dynamics at
progressively ascending spatial scales from
the local through the regional and the na-
tional to the supranational or global. This
strategy may be promoted from above and/or
may emerge from below. It is re ected dis-
cursively in attempts “to position places cen-
trally on ‘stages’ of various spatial scales:
regional, national, international, global”
(Hall and Hubbard, 1996, pp. 163–164). The
third option involves building what one
might call ‘transversal’ linkages—i.e. by-
passing one or more immediately neighbour-
ing scale(s) to seek closer integration with
processes on various other scales. This can
occur in cases such as export-processing
zones, free ports or regional gateways where
the links to an immediate hinterland or even
the national economy are less important than
the connection between local and suprana-
tional scales.
One relatively novel form of interurban
competition is ‘glurbanisation’. We have
coined this term to distinguish urban from
Ž rm-level strategies within the broader con-
cept of ‘glocalisation’, which has lost its
original precision as it has become the vogue
word for all kinds of multiscalar strategies
with at least some global aspect. As such it
clearly differs from the initial usage of glo-
calisation to distinguish the strategy of global
localisation pursued by Japanese Ž rms from
the strategy of globalisation favoured by
BOB JESSOP AND NGAI-LING SUM
2294
many US multinationals.5
In this context,
whereas globalisation is oriented to building
a worldwide intraŽ rm division of labour with
production oriented to world markets and
standard tastes, glocalisation is concerned
with establishing a geographically concen-
trated interŽ rm division of labour in the three
major trading blocs (Ruigrok and van Tulder,
1996, p. 180).6
These two contrasting glo-
bally oriented strategies can be distinguished
from export-oriented domestic production
with decentralised marketing; multidomestic
production based on establishing foreign pro-
duction on a country-by-country basis; screw-
driver assembly in one or more domestic
economies based on imported components;
macroregional divisions of labour within tri-
ads; and diadic division of labour strategies
oriented to relatively autonomous operations
in two macroregions (Ruigrok and van Tul-
der, 1996, pp. 181–182). No doubt further
strategies could be added that are oriented to
plurispatial and multiscalar operations across
different national economies. But the com-
mon feature of all these strategies is that they
are the strategies of potentially mobile Ž rms
and thus distinct from the multiscalar strate-
gies of cities or other immobile economic
units. This suggests that glocalisation will
have very different meanings for mobile and
immobile economic units—let alone for pol-
itical as opposed to economic units.
‘Glocalisation’ has also been used to de-
scribe deterritorialisation and reterritorialisa-
tion strategies by political units (see initially
the work of Swyngedouw, 1997, later Bren-
ner, 1997–99). But this is the other side of the
contradiction of mobility–immobility in capi-
tal accumulation and has a very different
dynamic. We suggest that it is more sensible
to differentiate strategies on the immobile
territorial side as well as on the mobile deter-
ritorialising or even aterritorial (i.e. cyber-)
side of the accumulation of capital. Failure to
do so leads to the conceptual morass of a
‘glocalisation’ concept that simply refers to
any and all forms of global–local interaction.
The problems involved here are well-
illustrated in Brenner’s otherwise excellent
work on ‘glocal’ states and ‘glocal’ cities.
Brenner relates his work to Lefebvre’s
notion of trial by space. This implies that
the viability of all strategies of capital
accumulation, modes of state regulation
and forms of socio-political mobilization
has come to depend crucially upon the
ability to produce, appropriate, organise,
restructure and control social space (Bren-
ner, 1997a, p. 1).
In this context, Brenner uses ‘glocal’ and its
cognates, ‘glocally oriented’ and ‘glocalisa-
tion’, to refer to at least four different phe-
nomena:
(1) The impact of the after-Fordist global–
local restructuring or rescaling of the
national territorial state so that it be-
comes a ‘glocal’ state—i.e. a polymor-
phic, hollowed-out, denationalised,
multitiered or multiscalar form of state
territorial organisation that is the na-
tional equivalent to the urban ‘exopolis’
as an expression of post-Fordist capital
accumulation.
(2) The ‘glocally oriented’ rescaling strate-
gies of national states to enhance the
locational advantages and productive ca-
pacities of cities and regions in their
territorial jurisdictions as maximally
competitive nodes in the global economy
and/or to enforce the devalorisation and
revalorisation of capital within declining
cities and regions.
(3) Changes in cities themselves as they be-
come massive, polycentric urban re-
gions, megalopolises or exopolises that
are turned ‘outside in’ and ‘inside out’
due to new global–local scale ge-
ometries, which entail an increasingly
dense ‘superimposition and interpenetra-
tion’ of multiple, overlapping sub-state
and suprastate scales.
(4) The internationalisation of policy
regimes through the roles of suprana-
tional agencies such as the EU, the IMF
and the World Bank in regulating and
restructuring the internal territorial
spaces of national states (Brenner,
1997a, 1997b, 1998, 1999a, 1999b).
AN ENTREPRENEURIAL CITY IN ACTION 2295
In using this term, Brenner sometimes focuses
on the ‘global–local’ couplet and sometimes
stresses the multiplicity of the scales of terri-
torial organisation that are involved in glocal-
isation. Nowhere does he refer to functional
scales or to the impact of cyberspace. In some
contexts, he also explains the emergence of
global–local state rescaling as a major stra-
tegic response to the political and administrat-
ive crises as well as to the economic crisis of
after-Fordism. And, in the latter regard, he
notes the speciŽ cally capitalist dialectic that
 uctuates around the contradiction between
capital’s constant striving to enhance its spa-
tial mobility by diminishing its place-
dependency and states’ attempts to Ž x capital
within their territories through the provision
of immobile, place-speciŽ c externalities than
either cannot be found elsewhere or cannot be
abandoned without considerable devalorisa-
tion costs to capital.
To avoid these problems, we propose the
term ‘glurbanisation’ strategies to refer to
entrepreneurial strategies that are concerned
to secure the most advantageous insertion of
a given city into the changing interscalar
division of labour in the world economy. For,
whilst glocalisation is a strategy pursued by
global Ž rms that seek to exploit local differ-
ences to enhance their global operations, glur-
banisation is pursued by cities to enhance
their place-based dynamic competitive advan-
tages to capture certain types of mobile capi-
tal and/or to Ž x local capital in place. More
recently, of course, glocalisation has been
used to refer to a wide range of strategies
associated with an equally diverse range of
actors that involve multiscalar strategies,
jumping scales between local and global or,
as noted above, transversal strategies.
The key analytical (and empirical) differ-
ences between glurbanisation and glocalisa-
tion as we propose them within the broader
framework of concerns with global–local (or,
better, multiscalar) articulation are sum-
marised in Table 1. This table is not intended
to present a complete typology of multiscalar
strategies, but aims simply to highlight some
differences important for the ensuing dis-
cussion.
In addition to noting the four analytical and
empirical distinctions between these two
strategies, we would recommend that glur-
banisation be analysed differently from the
manner in which glocalisation is usually stud-
ied.7
First, studies of glocalisation tend to
work with a crude global–local dichotomy
(even though actual Ž rm-, alliance- or net-
work-level glocalisation strategies are often
more sophisticated). This belies the multi-
scalar, multitemporal nature of globalisation.
Studies of glurbanisation should be attentive
from the outset to the multiplicity of scales,
including the creation of new scales of ac-
tivity that might weaken traditional ideas of
‘nested’ territoriality. Secondly, accounts of
glocalisation tend to privilege the spatial and
neglect the temporal dimension of Ž rm strate-
gies. In contrast, glurbanisation is explicitly
concerned with how time as well as space is
governed in the production of urban-based
competitive advantage. This is the aspect
listed in Table 1 as chronotopic governance
and one that we recommend be introduced
into glocalisation as well as glurbanisation
studies. Thirdly, whereas past studies of glo-
calisation tend to focus on the Ž rm- or sector-
speciŽ c competitive advantages that it
generates, future research on glurbanisation
should also include its impact on the extra-
economic dimensions of competitiveness. In
other words, it should address the issue of
structural or systemic competitiveness; and
this implies that the analysis of competition
would go beyond narrow economic issues to
include a wide range of ‘combinations’
(Schumpeter) that bridge the economic and
extra-economic. Fourthly, whereas analyses
of ‘glocalisation’ tend to emphasise its advan-
tages to Ž rms, our analysis is just as con-
cerned with the problems posed by
entrepreneurial activity. These include the
tendential exhaustion of the ‘rents’ derived
from any given entrepreneurial innovation (a
tendency already noted by Schumpeter), the
costs of ‘glurbanisation’ strategies for less
privileged or powerful groups and the typical
forms of failure of entrepreneurial city strate-
gies.
The concept of glurbanisation is very use-
2296 BOB JESSOP AND NGAI-LING SUM
Table
1.
Glurbanisation
versus
glocalisation
Glurbanisation
Glocalisation
Strategic
actors
Cities
(perhaps
as
national
champions)
Firms
(perhaps
in
strategic
alliances)
Strategies
Place-
and
space-based
strategies
Firm-
or
sector-based
strategies
New
scales
of
activities
Create
local
differences
to
capture
Develop
new
forms
of
scalar
and/or
and
temporalities

ows
and
embed
mobile
capital
spatial
division
of
labour
Chronotopic
governance
Re-articulate
time
and
space
for
structural
Re-articulate
global
and
local
for
dynamic
or
systemic
competitive
advantages
competitive
advantages
AN ENTREPRENEURIAL CITY IN ACTION 2297
ful for exploring the emerging strategies of
contemporary entrepreneurial cities. For it
complements the concept of glocalisation
and thereby provides a means of exploring
the articulation between Ž rm-level, city-level
and state-level strategies in the current period
of globalisation. It also highlights the con-
trasting moments of ‘glocalisation’ in its
broadest sense—i.e. the tendential deterrito-
rialising mobility of  ows in space versus
reterritorialising attempts to Ž x capital in
place. It is also highly relevant to the pursuit
of dynamic competitive advantage in so far
as ‘entrepreneurial cities’ must position
themselves not only in the economic sphere,
but also in the many extra-economic spheres
that are so important nowadays to effective
structural or systemic competition. In doing
so, they continue to reproduce local differ-
ences that enable transnational Ž rms to pur-
sue their own ‘glocalisation’ strategies.
3. An Entrepreneurial City in Action: The
Case of Hong Kong
Hong Kong has a long history of urban en-
trepreneurialism, with different strategies be-
ing pursued as its economic and political
environments changed. Our paper focuses on
the period since 1979—i.e. from the year that
China Ž rst opened its doors to foreign invest-
ment through to Hong Kong’s current efforts
to reposition itself in the light of the Asian
crisis. At stake here is a complex and still
evolving dialectic between glocalisation and
glurbanisation strategies in the broad sense in
which these terms have just been deŽ ned.
The opening of China provided opportunities
for Hong Kong Ž rms to adopt glocalisation
strategies to enhance their competitive ad-
vantage in the export market. This was partly
facilitated by the corresponding glurbanisa-
tion strategies of different provinces, cities
and townships in southern China. This
resulted in the so-called hollowing-out of
Hong Kong as a manufacturing centre. The
gap has been Ž lled by Hong Kong’s emerg-
ence as a services centre for local, regional
and international companies. In response to
these changes, governmental and quasi-
governmental as well as private economic
actors proposed their own (competing) glur-
banisation strategies for Hong Kong—some
more favourable to a reinvigorated manufac-
turing strategy, some more favourable to the
development of a producer service role
within a changing regional–global economy.
These ‘glurbanisation’ responses in Hong
Kong took a new turn with the outbreak of
the Asian crisis and its impact on interurban,
interregional and international competition in
east Asia and more widely. We develop these
ideas in the remainder of this paper.
3.1 ‘Glocalisation’ Strategies: From Industry
to Services
China’s declaration of its open door policy
was followed Ž ve years later by the signing
of the Sino–British Joint Declaration in 1984.
This promised that Hong Kong’s capitalist
way of life would not be changed for 50
years after its return to the mainland in 1997.
This provided a temporary calming effect on
Hong Kong society and thereby encouraged
manufacturers to look for short- to medium-
term opportunities in the immediate region.
In particular, taking advantage of the low
land and labour costs, manufacturing Ž rms
relocated their activities to southern China.
By the mid 1990s, almost 25 000 Hong Kong
factories, mostly in textiles and clothing, toys
and consumer electronics, moved there to
exploit low labour and rent costs. They then
employed directly about 3 million workers—
i.e. three times the total manufacturing
labour force left in Hong Kong.
The shifting of manufacturing northwards
was the result of the coalescence of glocali-
sation/glurbanisation strategies pursued by
various actors—private and public, economic
and political—in Hong Kong and the region.
More speciŽ cally, the Hong Kong govern-
ment, with its commercial and industrial
bases of support, continued with the so-
called positive non-intervention strategy to
enhance Hong Kong’s core commercial com-
petitive advantages. This is re ected in in-
creased emphasis on the provision of the
physical, organisational and informational
BOB JESSOP AND NGAI-LING SUM
2298
infrastructure for a developing gateway role;
a continuing commitment to low and simple
taxation; regulation of Ž nance and com-
merce; and the maintenance of Hong Kong’s
free port and free trade status. There is also
an interesting complementarity here between
the Hong Kong government’s strategy and
the PRC’s desire to attract FDI and exper-
iment with its growth-inducing potential. The
resulting decentralisation strategy allowed
Guangdong and Fujian to adopt preferential
treatments for Hong Kong and Taiwanese
investment in their development of a ‘glur-
banisation’ strategy (Nee, 1992; Sum, 1996,
pp. 60–62).
In response to these changes, Taiwan in-
dustrial and commercial capital also became
more interested in establishing commercial
links with the mainland through Hong Kong.
Moreover, following the depreciation of Tai-
wanese currency from 1986 onwards, the
rising cost of land and the high standards set
by the Taiwanese government’s 1984 Basic
Labour Law, Ž rms also became more inter-
ested in China as an industrial base. This
reorientation has since been promoted by the
KMT government itself on condition that
trade and the movement of factors of pro-
duction pass through a third site—which, in
practice, usually meant Hong Kong (with
Macau playing a secondary role). As a result,
Hong Kong and Taiwan are the two biggest
investors in Guangdong and Fujian provinces
with Hong Kong alone supplying 80 per cent
of all FDI. The region became a major pro-
duction base for its more labour-intensive
products aimed at the global market.
This regional production space is also co-
ordinated by private actors who are pursuing
various glocalisation strategies to rearticulate
time and space across borders. This is
re ected in the increasing importance at-
tached in Hong Kong at all levels of action to
the time–space dimensions of competition.
Thus, industrial and commercial capitals
from Hong Kong (and Taiwan) draw on their
linguistic afŽ nities and kinship ties to build
socioeconomic connections in the region.
They also enter strategic networks with vari-
ous local Chinese public, quasi-public and
private agencies in the region and consoli-
date them through the socio-cultural prac-
tices of guanxi (relationship). These cultural
time–space aspects of ‘Greater China’ help
to consolidate a coalition of local party/
administrative ofŽ cials, their afŽ liates and
Hong Kong (and Taiwanese) capital. They
form the social bases of support for a trans-
border division of labour as Hong Kong
shifts labour-intensive manufacturing to
southern China.
This process not only deepens Hong
Kong’s entrepôt role, but also enhances its
capacity as a global-regional gateway city to
co-ordinate investment, trade and services in
and beyond the ‘Greater China’ region.
Basing themselves in Hong Kong as a gate-
way city, the glocalisation strategies of capi-
tal involve a rearticulation of the chronotopic
dimensions of production, trade and Ž nance.
More speciŽ cally, Hong Kong’s industrial,
commercial and Ž nancial capital innovate
new organisational practices that can be use-
fully described as ‘sub-contracting manage-
ment’ which involves sourcing, production,
authority and distribution management. In
response to the demand for global out-
sourcing, industrial and commercial capital
locate Chinese partners through formal con-
tact and informal kinship and communal ties.
This intensiŽ cation of the social space
through guanxi helps to speed up the border-
crossing time across the private–public div-
ide as well as the rural–urban; and also to
build the mutual relations needed to establish
sub-contracting partnerships and joint ven-
tures. After establishing these sourcing net-
works, Hong Kong capital then engages in
production management across time and
space. The production process involves the
co-ordination and supervision of time-bound
projects dispersed across various sites with
the more skill-intensive sub-processes in
Hong Kong and the more labour-intensive
ones in southern China. Production man-
agers, quality controllers, line managers and
so forth from Hong Kong are at the forefront
here in rearticulating spatial scales and tem-
poral horizons to realise time-constrained
projects. This often involves further in-
AN ENTREPRENEURIAL CITY IN ACTION 2299
tensiŽ cation of production practices, such as
Ž ner differentiation of pre-production plan-
ning and greater intensiŽ cation of production
schedules and monitoring. Such practices
build the capacity to co-ordinate transborder
production processes so that goods reach the
global market just-in-time.
Also essential to this chronotopic gover-
nance network is the building of good rela-
tions with local/central ofŽ cials and cadre
entrepreneurs in China. After all, these au-
thorities still control enormous resources,
such as land, labour, capital and regulations.
In addition to production and authority man-
agement, Ž nished goods in the ‘supply
pipeline’ need to be exported/distributed to
the global market. Distribution management,
then, involves the rearticulation of factory
time and global lead-time through the activi-
ties of service-based Ž rms in the region as
well as trading and customs authorities. This
transborder private–public network is co-
ordinated in the ‘electronic’ and ‘social’
spaces that synchronise transport schedules,
export procedures of import/export licensing,
custom liaison, international payments, in-
surance, packaging and logistic management,
etc., so that goods can be delivered just-in-
time and ‘right-in-place’ for the global-
regional buyers. Practices such as these help
to speed up the transit- and pipeline-time
crucial to time-bound projects (Sum, 1999,
pp. 139–142).
The sub-contracting management practices
that are developed and co-ordinated across
the border by these various political and
economic actors are a form of process inno-
vation. The role of these actors and practices
in consolidating a cross-border ‘structured
coherence’ between mode of growth and
modes of regulation-governance lie at the
heart of urban entrepreneurialism in Hong
Kong. In this regard, Hong Kong’s competi-
tive advantages (for example, quick response
and lead-times for product procurement and
sub-contracting, great  exibility in order-
taking and product manufacturing, the ease
of international sourcing, the proximity and
ease of access to the PRC, the availability of
trade Ž nance) are embedded in these net-
works and their co-ordination of the indus-
trial, commercial, Ž nancial and cultural
forms of chronotopic governance. These ad-
vantages were created primarily by local
Ž rms and networks. This ensures the most
favourable insertion of Hong Kong as a city
into the emerging local–regional–global div-
ision of labour and makes it attractive
enough to capture and Ž x the global–regional
‘space of  ows’ in Hong Kong. In this re-
gard, Hong Kong’s emerging position as a
global-gateway city enables it to stay at the
leading edge of the ‘fast world’ (Knox and
Taylor, 1995) in an era of increasing ‘time-
based’ competition.
3.2 The ‘Hollowing Out’/‘Filling In’ of Hong
Kong
This combination of ‘glocalisation strategies’
pursued by Hong Kong Ž rms and a ‘glurban-
isation’ strategy pursued by provincial, urban
and township authorities in southern China
contributed to Hong Kong’s transformation
from an industrial centre to a global-gateway
city. But it also prompted the so-called hol-
lowing-out process in its status as a manufac-
turing centre. The resulting gap has been
Ž lled by the growing importance of producer
services such as retail and import/export
trades, Ž nancial services, insurance, real es-
tate and business services as well as owner-
ship of premises (see Table 2). Hong Kong’s
development as a service-based economy can
be analysed on the material and discursive
levels.
The emergence of Žnance and real estate
sectors. On the material level, the northward
march of Hong Kong’s manufacturing turned
it into a (sub-contracting) management hub.
This new ‘temporal–spatial Ž x’ for the indus-
trial and trade circuits has been coupled with
developments on the Ž nancial front, for,
since the early 1980s, Hong Kong has be-
come a regional Ž nancial centre. Among
contributory factors here are: Hong Kong’s
market-friendly environment; the opening of
China for inward and outward investment;
BOB JESSOP AND NGAI-LING SUM
2300
Table 2. SelectedGDPatcurrent pricesby economic activity(unit percentage)
1985 1990 1995 1997
Industry 29.8 25.3 16.6 14.7
Manufacturing 21.9 17.6 8.3 6.5
Construction 5.0 5.4 5.4 5.8
Others 2.9 2.3 2.9 2.4
Services 74.5 80.3 83.8 85.2
Wholesale/retail, import/export 21.8 24.3 26.6 26.1
trades, restaurants and hotels
Transport, storage and 8.1 9.4 10.1 9.3
communication
Financing, insurance, real estate 16.3 20.8 24.4 26.5
and business services
Community, social and 17.3 15.0 17.3 17.4
personal services
Ownership of premises 11.0 10.8 13.3 13.0
Sources: Hong Kong Annual Report, Hong Kong SAR Government
(various years).
the growing economic importance of the
Asia-PaciŽ c region; global Ž nancial liberali-
sation and development of international
banking and Ž nancial markets; and, develop-
ments in information technology and
telecommunications. Local, regional and
multinational banks/Ž nancial institutions
came to specialise in on-shore and off-shore
activities—for example, syndicated loans for
the south-east Asian region and acting as a
Ž nancial entrepôt for ‘Greater China’. As a
regional Ž nancial centre, Hong Kong became
a net recipient of overseas funds, which
amounted to about HK$138 billion in 1988.
About half of these funds came from Chinese
banks (Taylor, 1991, p. 48). In addition,
Ž nancial deregulation in Japan and tougher
competition among Japanese banks meant
that Hong Kong became one of their destina-
tions for off-shore activities. Thus, by the
end of 1989, Japanese institutions came to
dominate Hong Kong’s foreign-currency
loan market and accounted for 66 per cent of
Hong Kong’s total foreign currency assets
(Goldstein, 1990, p. 71).
This ample supply of funds was not easily
absorbed by Hong Kong’s immature debt
market. Thus excess capital was hunting for
a new Ž eld of capital accumulation. From
1984 to 1997, it was property that provided
this Ž eld. This was facilitated by the follow-
ing structural and conjunctural contexts:
(1) the Hong Kong government’s historical
dependency upon land and property-
related activities for 40 per cent of its
revenue;
(2) the pegged exchange rate between the
Hong Kong and the US dollars, which
meant that local interest rates were lower
than the rate of in ation;
(3) the low real interest rates, which made
property purchases attractive;
(4) the signing of the Sino–British Joint
Declaration in 1984, which allowed the
extension of land leases up to 2047;
(5) the accumulated hard currency from
mainland China searching for investment
outlets in Hong Kong;
(6) the growth in population during 1991–
93, due to an increase in the numbers of
returning emigrants, imported workers
and expatriates working in Hong Kong;
(7) the growth in GDP per capita income at
4.4 per cent per year between 1985 and
1997; and
(8) the desire of the new middle classes for
property, which was seen both as a sym-
AN ENTREPRENEURIAL CITY IN ACTION 2301
bol of better lifestyle and as a rational
hedge against 8 per cent annual in ation.
Together, these factors made property invest-
ment and speculation a way of life and not
just a form of business. Between 1985 and
1997, property estate investment and specu-
lation pushed real estate prices up eight-fold.
The emergence of property as an object of
capital accumulation has consolidated a close
relationship between Ž nance and property
capital. This can be seen in three key phe-
nomena: loan exposure of Ž nancial institu-
tions to construction and real estate in Hong
Kong averaged 40 per cent during 1983–97;
more than half of the Hang Seng Index is
made up of property and property-related
shares; and, well-developed interlocking di-
rectorships exist between banks and real es-
tate/infrastructural development companies
(for example, Li Ka-Shing was a deputy
chairman of Hongkong Bank as well as the
Chairman of Cheung Kong). This property–
Ž nance relationship formed only part of a
broader cross-border urban bloc that com-
prised not only multinational/local banks (in
the form of project Ž nance/mortgages) and
construction companies (in the form of land/
property assets) but also legal/property pro-
fessionals (in the form of services), the
government (in the form of land and rev-
enues), the middle classes (in the form of
newly acquired wealth and investment) and
cross-border capital from China (in the form
of legal and clandestine capital).
Competing discourses on Hong Kong’s glur-
banisation strategies: service versus indus-
try/Harvard versus MIT. This ‘Ž lling in’ of
Hong Kong has given rise to continuing
re exive discussions about Hong Kong’s
economic future. First, worries about the de-
cline of industry and the lack of high-tech
investment were voiced by industrial frac-
tions, especially the larger manufacturers (for
example, the Federation of Hong Kong In-
dustries). Secondly, rising residential and
ofŽ ce rental costs were rendering the service
sector vulnerable and this fraction was won-
dering how best to enhance its service-based
competitive advantages (for example, the
Hong Kong Chamber of Commerce and the
Hong Kong Coalition of Service Industries).
Such issues frequently triggered public de-
bates in the Legislative Councils, pro-
fessional meetings and the mass media.
Around 1996, these concerns were re ected
in the concurrent commissioning of two con-
sultancy reports that were sponsored and/or
supported by different fractions of capital,
public organisations (for example, the Trade
Development Council and the Hong Kong
Productivity Centre) and government depart-
ments (for example, the Trade and Industry
Departments). The two reports were pub-
lished in 1997 and represented alternative
glurbanisation strategies, each of which
sought to envision and promote new scalar
and temporal horizons for a capitalist restruc-
turing of the city. They thereby re ect public
debates on what constitutes the most advan-
tageous mode of inserting Hong Kong into
the changing multiscalar and multitemporal
division of labour. In turn, this involves
redeŽ ning the objects of Hong Kong’s en-
trepreneurialism, its forms of competitive-
ness and the ‘new combinations’ involved in
creating and sustaining its structural and sys-
temic competitiveness. Constructions of this
kind are always contested and different frac-
tions of capital and their associated interests/
networks are deeply involved in redeŽ ning
the changing geography of Hong Kong’s
competitiveness. In so far as a wide range of
economic, political and social forces come to
share one of these competing visions and
mobilise behind it, Hong Kong can be seen
as a re exive city committed to changing its
insertion into the changing global (dis)order.
The following accounts of two recent consul-
tancy reports on Hong Kong aim to demon-
strate the contested nature of ‘glurbanisation’
strategies of Hong Kong as an ‘entrepreneu-
rial city’.
The Ž rst study is a Harvard Business
School consultancy report entitled The Hong
Kong Advantage (Enright et al., 1997). This
report was sponsored by the Vision 2047
Foundation, which groups together commer-
cial and Ž nancial capital interests. This group
BOB JESSOP AND NGAI-LING SUM
2302
promotes a revisioning of Hong Kong’s fu-
ture time and space favouring its own inter-
ests. The report notes Hong Kong’s
manufacturing decline and the challenge of
interurban competition from Shanghai, Sin-
gapore, Taipei and Sydney. It promotes a
vision of the city’s new identity as a ‘busi-
ness/service/Ž nancial centre’ with ‘hub’
functions (see Table 3). In Schumpeterian
terms, it portrays Hong Kong as a new type
of urban economic space that will manage
ever-expanding global–regional–local  ows
of production and exchange. In this regard,
its entrepreneurial ambition is to establish a
‘beyond-the-gateway’ image, or, more
speciŽ cally, to offer a ‘new combination’ of
‘hub’ functions around a ‘knowledge-infor-
mation-based’ economy with access to main-
land China, Asia and the Asian-PaciŽ c
region (Enright et al., 1997, pp. 25 and 167–
187).
This urban entrepreneurialism remaps not
only Hong Kong’s spatial horizons, but also
its temporal horizons of action. Thus, as a
key global-regional ‘hub’, it will capture and
manage ‘ ows’ rather than continue to serve
as an export platform. The aim is to rearticu-
late relations among global, regional and
local traders/investors by organising interna-
tionally located systems of production, com-
bining inputs from a diversity of sources in
many different countries, managing a diver-
sity of supply outlets, furnishing the required
capital, technical support (design, construc-
tion, engineering, legal, Ž nancial) and in-
frastructural provisions (particularly real and
virtual port and transport facilities in south-
ern China and Asia). This central logistic
role would enable Hong Kong to co-ordinate
new temporal horizons that would relink:
factory and pipeline time crucial to time-
bound and compressed-time projects; and,
electronic time to tame the  ow of Ž nancial,
logistic information and service-based
knowledge across borders as well as across
the private–public divide.
These new spatio-temporal horizons of ac-
tion should, the report continues, be facili-
tated and mediated by new urban-based
institutional arrangements and practices.
Thus it refers to certain features of Hong
Kong’s entrepreneurial and/or governance
capacities that are socially embedded on the
interpersonal, institutional and societal lev-
els. On an interpersonal level, the “hustle and
commitment strategies” [sic] of Hong
Kong’s “merchant manufacturers” should be
combined with the embedded institutions of
“government as referee” and with the activi-
ties of “entrepreneurial and managerial
Ž rms” from Hong Kong and abroad (Enright
et al., 1997, pp. 45– 46, 127, and 34– 40).
These networks would be supported by an
existing societal ethos of “hard-working peo-
ple” but this entrepreneurial culture must
nonetheless be helped to win greater compet-
itiveness. This is to be achieved through the
provision of “inputs to industry” (p. 85) and
by promoting strategic clusters of industries
such as property, construction, infrastructure,
business and Ž nancial services, transport and
logistics, light manufacturing and trading,
and tourism. Such clusters and their linkages
enable them to “draw upon common skill
bases or inputs, and reinforce each other’s
competitive positions through dynamic inter-
action” (Enright et al., 1997, p. 95). In short,
this Porterian construction of Hong Kong’s
structural competitiveness promotes a space-
based and interscalar ‘glurbanisation’ strat-
egy to reinsert Hong Kong favourably into
changing  ows produced by regional and
global restructuring.
The MIT report, entitled Made by Hong
Kong (Berger and Lester, 1997), offers a
more place-based account of Hong Kong’s
entrepreneurial future (see Table 3). This
report is sponsored by industrial capital with
the support of certain parts of the bureauc-
racy (most notably the Hong Kong Govern-
ment Industry Department and the Hong
Kong Productivity Council). It portrays
Hong Kong as locked into a ‘made by Hong
Kong’ manufacturing trajectory—i.e. as or-
ganising the low-cost manufacture of ‘Hong
Kong’ goods in offshore locations such as
southern China and other parts of Asia. The
report argues that this trajectory will prove
“unsustainable” due to rising labour and land
costs in Guangdong province, to the “craze
2303
AN ENTREPRENEURIAL CITY IN ACTION
Table
3.
Two
competing
glurbanisation
strategies
for
Hong
Kong
as
an
‘entrepreneurial
city’
in
1997
The
Hong
Kong
Advantage
Made
by
Hong
Kong
Object(s)
of
Decline
of
manufacturing
From
‘Made
by
Hong
Kong’
entrepreneurial
Promote
trade,
Ž
nance
and
to
‘Made
in
Hong
Kong’
intervention
high-tech
industry
City
identity
Business/service/Ž
nance
centre
Hi-tech
manufacturing
centre
Information
hub
·
Brand-name
production
Logistic
hub
·
Original
design
manufacturing
Innovative
practices
Purpose
Manage
the

ows
Fix
capital/technology
in
place
New
scales
of
activities
Global
–
regional
–
local
Regional
–
local
technology
(re)articulation
diffusion
(with
hints
of
global)
New
temporal
horizons
Rearticulating
transit/pipeline
time
Research
and
training
time
Importance
of
electronic
time
for
higher-value
products
Development
of
electronic
time
New
governance
capacities
Dynamic
clusters
and
linkages
R&D
base
Property,
construction
Input
to
all
industries
Input
to
technology
·
Location
(proximity
to
China)
·
Government
fundings
·
Infrastructure
(airport,
port,
telecom)
·
Private
R&D
investment
·
Capital
and
Ž
nance
·
Incentives
for
research
·
Capital
goods
and
components
·
Information
services
and
technologies
·
Human
resources
·
Regional
and
international
specialists
Form
of
competitiveness
Space-based
and
interscalar
competitiveness
Place-based
form
of
competitiveness
Fraction(s)
of
capital
Commercial
and
Ž
nancial
capital
Industrial
capital
(and
its
associated
networks)
(and
its
associated
networks)
BOB JESSOP AND NGAI-LING SUM
2304
for property” in the region and to the com-
petitive challenge coming from Japan’s suc-
cessful organisation of its own regional
networks in the area (Berger and Lester,
1997, pp. 52–57).
The best response to such uncertainties
for Hong Kong is said to be ‘climb the
technology ladder’ by producing higher-
value-added goods in Hong Kong itself. The
report deploys the symbols of ‘Made in Hong
Kong’ and Hong Kong as a ‘high-tech manu-
facturing centre’ to reorient its future com-
petitiveness and urban character. Seen in
Schumpeterian terms, this reconstruction
seeks to narrate Hong Kong in terms of a
new type of urban economic space that seeks
to ‘reŽ x’ its role as a base for production.
The invocation of ‘technology’ is the key
symbol here in building ‘Hong Kong’s
new engine for growth’. And this will in-
volve a different chronotopic Ž x from that
involved in the previous ‘made by Hong
Kong’ mode of growth. It involves new
methods of producing and organising socio-
economic space and will require the support
of government.
Spatially, the team envisions a global–
regional–local diffusion of technology that
could launch Hong Kong on the path to its
own brand-name production and original de-
sign manufacturing. This place-based com-
petitiveness involves intensifying (including
compressing) research and training time as
well as exploiting possibilities in electronic
time. This remixing of time–space horizons
requires  ows of information conducive to
the development of an R&D base crucial to
Hong Kong’s competitiveness. This in turn
requires new urban-based institutional ar-
rangements and practices. Accordingly, the
report concentrates on institutional changes
required to boost the entrepreneurial and
self-governance capacities of Hong Kong’s
technological base. These include:
(1) acquiring technical knowledge from the
PRC, diasporic Chinese, international
experts and multinational corporations;
(2) promoting R&D agglomeration econom-
ies based on universities, technology-
based enterprises, education institutes,
(virtual) science parks and private Ž rms;
(3) acquiring new inputs such as govern-
ment fundings, human resources and in-
formation technology; and
(4) strengthening the technological capabili-
ties of government by injecting more
technical expertise and raising the proŽ le
of technology-related policies; etc.
In short, we can argue that this construction
of Hong Kong’s structural competitiveness is
based on a place-based notion.
4. The Asian Crisis and Hong Kong’s New
Urban Identities
These competing ‘glurbanisation’ visions re-
veal the contested nature of Hong Kong’s
urban restructuring and its embedded social
and economic relations. This debate was,
however, interrupted by Hong Kong’s tran-
sition from a British colony to a Special
Administrative Region in 1997; and, more
importantly and unexpectedly, by the Asian
crisis as it unfolded in 1997–99.
4.1 The Asian Crisis
On February 1997, speculators Ž rst attacked
the Thai bhat and the Bank of Thailand
allowed the bhat to  oat on 2 July 1997. This
triggered a Ž nancial contagion that quickly
spread from Thailand to Indonesia, Malaysia,
South Korea, the Phillippines, and then Hong
Kong (Sum, 1999). In Hong Kong, the dollar
came under speculative pressure on several
occasions in July, August and October 1997.
These currency attacks put the government
on short-term crisis management. It inter-
vened in the money market initially by push-
ing up interest rates in the interbanking
sector and later by imposing penalty interest
on borrowing of the Hong Kong dollar. The
government was able to maintain the pegged
exchange rate under conditions of high inter-
est rates, capital  ight from the Hong Kong
dollar and reduced external demand. These
pushed the local stock index and residential
AN ENTREPRENEURIAL CITY IN ACTION 2305
property prices down by over 50 per cent
between October 1997 and June 1998. This
asset depreciation, especially in the property
sector, cut at the heart of Hong Kong’s inter-
nal ‘growth’ dynamics, since this had devel-
oped since the opening of China. This
bursting of the ‘property bubble’ has given
rise to fear among this property-related bloc
about further asset depreciation. In order to
prevent the asset from further depreciating,
the government’s short-term strategies were:
to freeze land sales (until April 1999); to
allocate HK$1390 million for home-buyer
loans; and, to grant tax rebates to property
owners.
The Hong Kong dollar came under further
attack in August 1998 when the yen depreci-
ated against the dollar, with hedge funds
selling the Hong Kong stock market short in
the expectation that the index would fall as
interest rates rose. Speculative attacks pro-
pelled signiŽ cant amounts of capital out ow
as some people believed that this might also
force a yuan devaluation. This time, the
government reacted with more short-term
measures which included: drawing on its re-
serves to buy US$ 15 billion worth of se-
lected Hong Kong shares (60 per cent of
these were property related—higher than this
sector’s weight in the stock market); and,
introducing a package of technical measures
to strengthen the transparency and operation
of the linked exchange rate system (for ex-
ample, a rediscount facility to reduce interest
rate volatility). The pegged system was once
again maintained, but at the expense of high
interest rates, weak domestic demand and
rising unemployment. Hong Kong’s GDP
fell 5 per cent and the unemployment rate
had reached 6 per cent at the beginning of
1999. However, wages and rents are still
high. In April 1999, the government resumed
land sales—an action that was seen as a
continuing of its support for the property
sector. These are short-term tactics that seek
to maintain the conŽ dence of the property-
related urban bloc. However, the debate over
what constitutes Hong Kong’s ‘glurbanisa-
tion strategy’ and new urban identity is far
from being over.
4.2 A New Urban Identity for a Crisis-ridden
Hong Kong
The service versus industry (or Harvard ver-
sus MIT) debate took a new turn when the
crisis began to stabilise in early 1999. The
Asian crisis has disarticulated the previous
structured coherence of Hong Kong’s politi-
cal economy and has exposed it to several
challenges:
(1) the decline in Hong Kong’s role as agent
for China’s exports;
(2) over-dependence on property sector;
(3) the vulnerability of Ž nancial and other
services;
(4) the effects of recession (see, for exam-
ple, negative growth rate, fall in asset
values 6 per cent unemployment rate);
(5) competition from other regional cities,
such as Shanghai and Singapore; and
(6) the rising ‘tide of the information revol-
ution’.
Given that Hong Kong has become a global–
regional–gateway city dependent on the local
real estate sector as well as cross-border
manufacturing, innovative attempts to recast
Hong Kong’s competitiveness cannot be en-
tirely divorced from this historical growth
path. Up to the time of writing, private and
public actors alike are urgently seeking to
construct new objects and projects of urban
governance that might help to rebuild the
crisis-ridden economy. One high-proŽ le ob-
ject-project is the ‘Cyberport’ (see Table 4)
that was originally the ‘brain child’ of ‘Hong
Kong’s Bill Gates’ (Richard Li) and his
Singapore-based corporation called PaciŽ c
Century.
Li’s (and PaciŽ c Century’s) idea was to
create
a comprehensive facility designed to foster
the development of Hong Kong’s infor-
mation services sector and to enhance
Hong Kong’s position as the premier in-
formation and telecommunications hub in
Asia (Hong Kong Cyberport, 1999, p. 1).
In addition,
the Cyber-port is meant to attract, nurture
BOB JESSOP AND NGAI-LING SUM
2306
Table 4. A new economic object of urban governance: Cyberport
Cost HK$13 billion (US$1.68 billion)
Size 64 acres (25.6 hectares)
Location Telegragh Bay, Pokfulam
Aims “To create a world class location for the conduct of a
variety of activities which through the use of information
technologies, can leverage Hong Kong existing strengths
in the service sector (e.g., in Ž nancial, media, retail,
transportation, education, and tourism services)”
(Hong Kong Cyberport, 1999, p. 1).
Built Environment I Cyber facilities (2/3 of the site)
Fibre-optic wiring
Satellite signal senders
Built-in high-speed modems
Cyberlibrary
Media laboratories and studio facilities
Built Environment II Real estate (1/3 of the site)
Houses and apartments
Hotels
Retail
Completion date 2007 (commencing from 2002)
Job creation 4 000 during construction
12 000 professional jobs on completion
(10 per cent from outside Hong Kong)
Partners PaciŽ c Century CyberWorks (HK$7 billion equity capital)
Government (land worth HK$6 billion)
Cluster of tenants Multinational corporations (Microsoft, IBM, Oracle,
HP, Softbank, Yahoo!, Hua Wei, Sybase)
Local tenants of small to medium-sized
information-technology companies
Metaphors/images used ‘Silicon Valley’ and ‘catching up’
and retain the relevant innovative talent
necessary to build a cyber-culture critical
mass in Hong Kong (Hong Kong Cyber-
port, 1999, p. 1).
In this regard, Li’s (and PaciŽ c Century’s)
vision is interesting in two aspects. First, it
can be seen as a re exive reinvention of the
Harvard report. It adopts the idea of a ser-
vice-based cluster; but one that narrates it in
terms of the metaphor ‘Silicon Valley’ and
suggests that the Cyberport could help Hong
Kong to ‘catch up’ with the ‘information
revolution’. In other words, the creation of
the Cyberport as an economic object can
rearticulate Hong Kong’s imagined time and
space not only to global-regional ‘trade and
Ž nancial  ows’ but also to global ‘infor-
mation  ows’.
More speciŽ cally, this project aims to
redeŽ ne Hong Kong’s competitive advan-
tages and chronotopic governance by: captur-
ing global ‘information  ows’ and managing
them within the service-space of Hong Kong
and its broader region (for example, as an
e-commerce hub); connecting Hong Kong’s
services to fast cybertime and the knowl-
edge-based economy; and, consolidating a
social space in which to build a ‘cyber cul-
ture critical mass’ that links the global, re-
gional and local. This time–space
reimagination can be seen as an innovative
AN ENTREPRENEURIAL CITY IN ACTION 2307
entrepreneurial city vision to create a new
techno-urban identity.
Secondly, given that the Cyberport is an
imagined service cluster that will be built to
capture the information-technology  ows,
this new object can symbolically (and, per-
haps, materially) bridge the traditional ser-
vice–technology–property divide in the
cityspace of Hong Kong. It highlights the
role of (information) technology in expand-
ing the activities of traditional service clus-
ters—a critical mass can be (partly) nurtured
by the physical form of the built environment
that is modelled on the ‘Silicon Valley’. The
transversal potential of this construction has
not gone unnoticed by the government and
its advisory agency (the Commission for
Innovation and Technology). In fact, the idea
was selected and (partly) appropriated by the
government when the Financial Secretary
unveiled it in the 1999 Budget.
After the ofŽ cial announcement, this new
object of urban governance seems to have
resonated within a global–regional–local
epistemic community comprising local capi-
tal (for example, Richard Li and the PaciŽ c
Century), the government (for example, the
Chief Executive, the Financial Secretary, the
Commission on Innovation and Technology,
the Secretary for Information and Broadcast-
ing), quasi-governmental organisations (for
example, Hong Kong Industrial Technology
Centre) and global–regional capitals (for ex-
ample, Microsoft’s Bill Gates, Yahoo!’s
Jerry Yeung and IBM’s Craig Barrett). The
latter group of ‘cyber-gods’  ew to Hong
Kong, publicly endorsed the idea and even
highlighted their own roles therein. A tech-
nocultural regime of truth is beginning to
emerge in this network of ‘infopreneurs’,
which cuts across the private–public as well
as global–regional–local spheres.
But this emerging regime of truth has also
encountered resistance. Some market ana-
lysts (for example, Webb) criticise the Cy-
berport idea as comprising little more than
“Cyber villas by sea” (i.e. a real estate proj-
ect as opposed to a high-tech project) and
claim there “is no ‘Silicon Valley’ ” (Webb,
1999). Being left out of an important stra-
tegic project, 10 real estate developers jointly
denounced the government’s decision-mak-
ing process as being ‘not open for bidding’
and declared that the government is using
residential land to subsidise the Cyberport
project. The Democratic Party, for different
reasons, challenged the government for lack
of transparency, creating ‘favouritism/
cronyism’ and departing from its ‘laissez-
faire’ policy.
Despite these challenges, the emerging
techno-urban discourse/identity continues to
resonate and has gathered some strength in
reorganising and reregularising economic
practices. Notable examples include new
consortia of property developers proposing
new innovative projects. Large developers
such as Sun Hung Kai Properties (SHKP)
and Hutchison Whampoa have reinvented
themselves as Internet companies. SHKP
created its own Internet arm (SunEvision)
and, together with the Hong Kong Industrial
Technology Centre (HKITC), launched the
Cyberincubator project in August 1999. Un-
der this latter scheme, developers would pro-
vide rent-free space for new ‘infopreneurs’
for 3 years in return for 10 per cent stakes in
their businesses. Other developers such as
Cheung Kong (Holdings), Henderson Land
Development, New World Development and
Sino Land are planning to participate in simi-
lar rent-for-equity programmes. The Chief
Executive, Tung Chee-Hwa, visited Silicon
Valley in July 1999 to build new linkages
with the local Internet communities. The
Hong Kong-Silicon Valley Association,
which is mediated by a Chinese diaspora
network, was set up to enhance possible glo-
bal–local  ows of knowledge, expertise and
manpower. Some investors even switched
from blue chips to Internet and technology
and Internet-related stocks—the share price
of PaciŽ c Century CyberWorks rose 1280
per cent when it Ž rst came onto the market in
May 1999.8
In this regard, it can be argued
that the technocultural imagination has cre-
ated a post-crisis euphoria that may be con-
ducive towards the rebuilding of a new form
of urban governance that cuts across the
global–regional–local scales as well as across
BOB JESSOP AND NGAI-LING SUM
2308
different fractions of commercial, Ž nancial,
property and technological capital. In ad-
dition to its potential to re-ally different cap-
itals (and their organisational and
interorganisational setups) for new strategic
projects, it is also facilitating the rebuilding
of cross-border private–public alliance based
on the politics of (Internet) optimism.
Riding on this politics of (Internet) opti-
mism, the Cyberport imagination was further
reinforced and broadened in the Second and
Final Report of the Commission of Inno-
vation and Technology published in June
1999. Acknowledging the importance of In-
ternet-based services linked to the Cyberport
project, the Commission reintroduces some
place-based manufacturing recommenda-
tions—some of which resonate with the MIT
report (for example, institutional/organisa-
tional changes such as institutional arrange-
ments, building up human capital, fostering
innovation and technology culture, and cre-
ating an enabling business environment).
However, it is also re exively seeking new
niches that would go beyond the MIT sug-
gestions. More speciŽ cally, one such niche
recommended by the Commission is the
building of a ‘Silicon Harbour’. This was
planned to comprise a semi-conductor manu-
facturing project that would allegedly be able
to ‘leapfrog’ existing microchip fabrication
facilities. This state-of-the-art factory would
cost US$1.2 billion and comprise 4 factories
built in phases, along with infrastructure and
supporting facilities, on over 200 hectares
and would eventually accommodate 200–300
companies. Its main aim was to by-pass the
PC age and enter directly into the ASICs
(application-speciŽ c integrated circuits) era
by 2003.9
This reintroduction of high-tech
manufacturing strategy back to Hong Kong
is not without sceptics, who see the chip-
manufacturing venture as going in the op-
posite direction from a service-based
e-commerce and information highway. In-
deed, at the time of writing, it seems unlikely
that the Silicon Harbour project will be
realised.
More recently (February 2000), the Com-
mission on Strategic Development, with the
approval of the Chief Executive, has rein-
forced the importance of the Ž nancial and
business services sector. This is illustrated by
an ofŽ cial blueprint for transforming Hong
Kong into Asia’s ‘world city’ that would
rival the positions of London and New York
in Europe and North America respectively.
This would involve strengthening Hong
Kong’s links with the Pearl River delta and
other mainland regions (such as the Yangtze
delta and basin and key central and western
regions) as well as enhancing its ability to
exploit China’s imminent entry into the
World Trade Organisation and position itself
as a ‘knowledge-based economy’. This blue-
print envisages a complex array of private–
public partnerships and networks
co-operating under Hong Kong’s leadership
to promote the overall competitiveness of an
emerging multicentred city-region, not only
in economic terms but also in cultural and
community matters. This long-term develop-
ment plan is explicitly phrased in en-
trepreneurial terms, emphasises the
importance of marketing Hong Kong as a
world-class city and is strongly committed to
promoting a wide range of innovative, high-
tech Ž nancial and business services to secure
its position within an evolving interscalar
division of labour (Commission on Strategic
Development, 2000).
5. Hong Kong and its New Interurban
Competition: The Siliconisation of Asia
Hong Kong is not the only city that has
imagined an information-technology fu-
ture—whether service- or manufacturing-
based. Inspired and worried by the hi-tech
boom in the US, other major cities in east
Asia are caught in this technology race. Gov-
ernments and different fractions/scales of
capital—for example, venture capital funds,
investment banks, real-estate companies, In-
ternet (mega-)corporations—in different ur-
ban centres co-ordinate and market
themselves by offering different ‘temporal–
spatial’ Ž xes that are related to some form of
hi-tech settlement such as Singapore’s ‘Intel-
AN ENTREPRENEURIAL CITY IN ACTION 2309
Table 5. Hi-tech clusters in Singapore and Malaysia
Singapore’s Malaysia’s
Science Hub Multi-media Supercorridor
Project cost US$20 billion US$2.9 billion
Size 434 acres 750 sq kma
Major tenants Dell Microsoft
National University of Singapore Intel
Singapore Polytechnic Nippon Telegraph and Telephone
Completion date Before 2013 (Ž rst phase in 2002) 2020
Niches R&D development Software
Multimedia products
a
The Supercorridor connects Kuala Lumpur and its airport.
ligent Island’ and ‘Science Hub’, Malaysia’s
‘Multimedia Supercorridor’ (see Table 5).
Singapore, a long-standing threat to Hong
Kong’s aim of becoming the dominant re-
gional Ž nancial centre, is entering a new
round of competition in the information age.
As early as 1986, Singapore formulated its
Ž rst national IT plan to enhance competitive-
ness. In 1991, the National Computer Board
initiated the IT2000 vision. This examined
how IT might be leveraged to improve busi-
ness performance and the quality of life. In
1996, the Singapore ONE (One Network for
Everybody) was announced with the aim of
establishing Singapore as the world’s ‘intelli-
gent island’ modelled upon the ‘Silicon Val-
ley’. This project involves building the
world’s Ž rst nation-wide broadband network
that wires up the entire island. This national
network aims to deliver a new level of inter-
active, multimedia applications and services
to its new breed of ‘netizens’. Up to 1999,
the total number of users was about 70 000.
More recently, Singapore has proposed a
‘Science Hub’ that aims to attract hi-tech
companies to engage in R&D development
(see Table 5).
In 1996, Malaysia’s Prime Minister, Ma-
hathir Mohamad, launched the idea of a
‘Multimedia Supercorridor’ (MSC) as the
country’s new ‘thrust area for sustainable
growth’ (see Table 5). It covers 750 sq km
stretching south from the federal capital to
the new Kuala Lumpur International Airport
and also encompasses Putrajaya, the govern-
ment’s new administrative centre. Its aim is
to become a test-bed for IT and multimedia
solutions. In July 1999, the Ž rst township,
Cyberjaya, was launched claiming to be a
‘Far East version of Silicon Valley’ which is
‘intelligent, hi-tech, low-density and environ-
mentally friendly’. It would also be the
MSC’s ‘nerve centre’ housing hi-tech com-
panies, research centres and a multimedia
university (Agence France Presse, 1999). It
has already attracted 21 companies to form
the core and is offering tax breaks and fast
communication links to attract the regional
headquarters of existing multinational com-
panies as well as new communication and
multimedia Ž rms.
Scattered around Asia, there are other
planned information technology clusters—
for example, Beijing’s Zhongguancun area.
They are at some stage of high-proŽ le devel-
opment, each one a self-proclaimed ‘next
Silicon Valley’ with a ‘Silicon Valley state
of mind’. This process of siliconisation in
east/south-east Asia marks one of the ways
these cities aim to compete. Each is launch-
ing an aggressive public-relations campaign
both locally and internationally to market a
niche that goes beyond its (current or future
diminishing capacity to provide) cheap land
and labour. At the time of writing, the Singa-
pore ONE is feeling the pinch from the fast-
track approach of Hong Kong’s Cyberport
and Malaysia’s Multimedia Supercorridor.
BOB JESSOP AND NGAI-LING SUM
2310
Thus Singapore ONE is now seeking to re-
gain the initiative by boosting its usage and
consolidating additional global–local partner-
ships that might wish to use Singapore as a
springboard to other broadband cities in Asia
(James, 1999).
6. Conclusions
The analysis presented above is still prelimi-
nary for two reasons. It is based on an
emerging approach to entrepreneurial cities
that needs further theoretical development
and reŽ nement; and it is illustrated from case
studies that are still at the early stages of
design and implementation. Nonetheless we
believe that four themes are worth restating
as key elements in an emerging research
agenda on interurban competition in the cur-
rent period of capitalist restructuring.
First, we believe that the crisis of the
national framework of the ‘spatio–temporal
Ž x’ and compromise that helped to sustain
post-war growth during the period of At-
lantic Fordism and the emergence of national
security and/or developmental states in east
Asia has contributed to a ‘relativisation of
scale’. This phenomenon refers to the fact
that no new scale has emerged to replace the
primacy of the national level in the organis-
ation and regularisation of the global econ-
omy. This is associated with the search for
new forms of chronotopic (time–space) gov-
ernance as well as new forms of material and
immaterial economic, political and social or-
ganisation. Indeed, we Ž nd competing spatial
and scalar strategies on many different lev-
els, pursued by a wide range of actors; but
these have not yet evolved into an overall
pattern of structural coherence analogous to
the post-war period with its primacy of the
national.
Secondly, in exploring the changing role
of cities in this regard, we believe that it is
useful to develop a Schumpeterian analysis
of the entrepreneurial city. We believe that it
is justiŽ ed to treat cities as actors under
certain conditions and that these are closely
bound up with capacities to realise particular
discursive-material accumulation strategies
and hegemonic projects. Even if this is re-
jected, it is certainly the case that urban blocs
claiming to speak for and on behalf of cities
or regions as ‘spaces for themselves’ (Lipi-
etz, 1985/1994) have become more explicitly
entrepreneurial on all three criteria intro-
duced above.
Thirdly, in this context we believe it is
worth distinguishing between ‘glocalisation’
and ‘glurbanisation’ in terms of whether it is
a Ž rm-level or city-level strategy that is at
stake. We concede that both terms are mis-
leading in so far as they seem to operate with
a simple global–local or a simple global–
urban dichotomy, which thereby fails to
grasp the real complexity and perplexity of
the proliferation of increasingly tangled
places, spaces and scales which can no
longer be treated as if they were ‘nested’ like
so many Russian dolls. But it is this very
complexity, perplexity, proliferation and tan-
gledness that poses uncertainties and risks
demanding new entrepreneurial orientations.
The concept of ‘glurbanisation’ represents a
Ž rst attempt to address some of these prob-
lems from the viewpoint of the city as actor
rather than from the viewpoint of the Ž rm.
As we have also noted elsewhere, however,
‘glurbanisation’ can also be seen as a state-
level response in so far as cities are coming
to replace Ž rms as ‘national champions’ in
international competition (Jessop, 1998;
Jessop and Sum, 1998).
Fourthly, we also relate these changes to
shifts in the modalities of competition in an
increasingly ‘globally integrated’ but still
multiscalar, unevenly developing and tangled
economy, because these shifts have modiŽ ed
the nature of interurban as well as inter-
national competition. Indeed, with the in-
creasing interest in dynamic competitive
advantages and the bases of structural and/
or systemic competitiveness, the extra-
economic dimensions of cities have gained
as much signiŽ cance as what used to be seen
as their economic dimensions. So-called
natural economic factor endowments have
become far less important (despite the con-
tinuing path-dependent aspects of the posi-
tioning of places in urban hierarchies); and
AN ENTREPRENEURIAL CITY IN ACTION 2311
socially constructed, socially regularised and
socially embedded factors have become more
important for interurban competitiveness.
This is why urban entrepreneurialism comes
to be so signiŽ cant in shaping the forms of
urban hierarchies (especially in their middle
ranks) and the character of global city net-
works. Certainly the capacity to remain at the
top of the hierarchy or to move up it depends
on cities’ capacities and strategies for acquir-
ing complex strategic activities and/or pro-
moting innovation in the areas we have
sketched (see Krätke, 1995, pp. 136–142).
Notes
1. On earlier power blocs and fractions of
capital, see Sum (1995).
2. On the now superseded proposal for a sci-
ence park, see Wong (1998). Another project
is the Disneyland Themepark which is being
promoted in Hong Kong in rivalry with
Shanghai.
3. For a rational choice approach to en-
trepreneurial cities that does make these (un-
realistic) assumptions, see Peterson (1981).
4. These boundaries are not necessarily singular
or coincident; they can be eccentric and in-
volve linkages with an eccentric hierarchy of
other scales.
5. On this initial usage, see Japan Machinery
Exporters’ Association, 1989, cited in
Ruigrok and van Tulder, 1996, p. 178n.
6. Glocalisation has also been used to refer to a
company’s attempt to become accepted as a
‘local citizen’ in a different trade bloc, while
transferring as little control as possible over
its areas of strategic concern’ (Ruigrok and
van Tulder, 1996, p. 179).
7. These recommendations could also be fruit-
fully applied to glocalisation.
8. CyberWorks was formerly known as Tricom
Holdings. It is an arm of the PaciŽ c Century
and is responsible for the Cyberport project.
It has since been listed on the Hong Kong
Stock Exchange as PaciŽ c Century Cyber-
Works.
9. ASICs are used to produce mobile phones,
handheld computers, smart blender and intel-
ligent microwave ovens and are expected to
replace PCs as the chief growth engine.
References
AGENCE FRANCE PRESS (1999) Multimedia charts
new growth path for Malaysia, 8 July
(wysiwyg://38/http:www.globalarchive.ft.com/
search/FTJSPController.ht).
BARNES, W. R. and LEDUBUR, L. C. (1991) To-
ward a new political economy of metropolitan
regions, Environment and Planning C, 9,
pp. 127–141.
BERGER, S. and LESTER, R. (1997) Made by Hong
Kong. Hong Kong: Oxford University Press.
BRAUDEL, F. (1984) The Perspective of the World.
London: Collins.
BRENNER, N. (1997a) Global cities, glocal states:
global city formation and state territorial re-
structuring in contemporary Europe, Review of
International Political Economy, 5, pp. 1–37.
BRENNER, N. (1997b) State territorial restructuring
and the production of spatial scale: urban and
regional planning in the Federal Republic of
Germany, 1960–1990, Political Geography, 16,
pp. 273–306.
BRENNER, N. (1998) Re-scaling state space:
urban regions, uneven development, and the
contradictory political geography of neoliber-
alism. Paper prepared for the RIPE conference
on ‘Globalisation, State, Violence’, University
of Sussex, April.
BRENNER, N. (1999a) Globalisation as reterritori-
alisation: the re-scaling of urban governance in
the European Union, Urban Studies, 36,
pp. 431–451.
BRENNER, N. (1999b) Beyond state-centrism?
Space, territoriality and geographical scale in
globalization studies, Theory and Society, 28,
pp. 39–78.
CASTELLS, M (1997) The Rise of Network Society.
Oxford: Blackwell.
CHESNAIS, F. (1986) Science, technology and
competitiveness, STI Review, 1, pp. 85–129.
CLARKE, S. and GAILE, G. (1998) The Work
of Cities. Minneapolis, MI: University of
Minnesota Press.
COMMISSION ON STRATEGIC DEVELOPMENT (2000)
Bringing the Vision to Life: Hong Kong’s
Long-term Development Needs and Goals.
Hong Kong: Central Policy Unit, Hong Kong
Special Administrative Region.
COX, K. R. and MAIR, A. (1991) From localised
social structures to localities as agents,
Environment and Planning A, 23, pp. 197– 214.
DALY, G. (1993) The discursive construction of
economic space, Economy and Society, 20,
pp. 79–102.
ENRIGHT, M., SCOTT, E. and DODWELL, D. (1997)
The Hong Kong Advantage. Hong Kong:
Oxford University Press.
GOLDSTEIN, C. (1990) High stakes: Japanese share
of overseas investment surges, Far Eastern
Economic Review, 28 June, pp. 71–72.
HALL, P. (1998) Cities and Civilisation. London:
Weidenfeld & Nicolson.
HALL, T. and HUBBARD, P. (1996) The en-
BOB JESSOP AND NGAI-LING SUM
2312
trepreneurial city: new urban politics, new
urban geographies?, Progress in Human
Geography, 20, pp. 153–174.
HARDING, A. (1995) European city regimes? In-
ter-urban competition in the new Europe. Paper
presented to an Economic and Social Research
Council Local Governance Conference, Exeter,
September.
HARVEY, D. (1989) From managerialism to en-
trepreneurialism: the transformation of urban
governance in late capitalism, GeograŽ ska
Annaler, Series B: Human Geography, 71B(1),
pp. 3–17.
HONG KONG CYBERPORT (1999) Hong Kong
Cyber-port (http://www.cyber-port.com/; read
on 9 June).
JACOBS, J. (1984) Cities and the Wealth of
Nations. Harmondsworth: Penguin.
JAMES, K. (1999) Singapore ONE Shifting to
Higher Gear, Singapore Business Times, 30
August.
JESSOP, B. (1997) The entrepreneurial city:
re-imaging localities, redesigning economic
governance, in: N. JEWSON and S. MACGREGOR
(Eds) Realizing Cities: New Spatial Divisions
and Social Transformation, pp. 28– 41. London:
Routledge.
JESSOP, B. (1998) The enterprise of narrative and
the narrative of enterprise: place marketing and
the entrepreneurial city, in: T. HALL and P.
HUBBARD (Eds) The Entrepreneurial City,
pp. 7–99. Chichester: Wiley.
JESSOP, B. (1999) The changing governance of
welfare: recent trends in its primary functions,
scale, and modes of coordination, Social Policy
and Administration, 33, pp. 348–359.
JESSOP, B. and SUM, N.-L. (1998) Interscalar
strategies in a ‘glurbanizing’ city: chronotopic
governance and urban entrepreneurship in
Hong Kong. Paper presented at the Inter-
national Workshop on ‘Globalizing Asian
Cities’, Helsinki, May. (Paper available from
either author.)
JONAS, A. E. G. and WILSON, D. (Eds) (1999) The
Urban Growth Machine: Critical Perspectives
Two Decades Later. New York: State Univer-
sity of New York Press.
KNOX, P. and TAYLOR, P. J. (Eds) (1995) World
Cities in a World System. Cambridge:
Cambridge University Press.
KRÄTKE, S. (1995) Stadt, Raum, Ökonomie: Ein-
führung in aktuelle Problemfelder der Stad-
tökonomie und Wirtschaftsgeographie. Basel:
Birkhäuser Verlag.
LE GALÈS, P. and HARDING, A. (1998) Cities and
states in Europe, West European Politics,
21(3), pp. 120–145.
LEICHT, K. T. and JENKINS, J. C. (1994) Three
strategies of state economic development:
entrepreneurial, industrial recruitment, and
deregulation policies in the American states,
Economic Development Quarterly, 8, pp. 256–
269.
LIM, C. Y. (1990) The Schumpeterian road to
af uence and communism, Malaysian Journal
of Economic Studies, 27, pp. 213– 223.
LIPIETZ, A. (1985/1994) The national and the
regional: their autonomy vis-à-vis the capitalist
world crisis, in: R. P. PALEN and B. GILLS (Eds)
Transcending the State–Global Divide: A Neo-
statist Agenda in International Relations,
pp. 23– 43. Boulder, CO: Lynne Rienner.
MESSNER, D. (1996) Die Netzwerkgesellschaft:
Wirtschaftliche Entwicklung und internationale
Wettbewerbsfähigkeit als Probleme
gesellschaftlicher Steuerung. Köln: Weltforum
Verlag.
NEE, V. (1992) Organisational dynamics of mar-
ket transitions: hybrid forms of property rights,
and mixed economy in China, Administrative
Science Quarterly, 37, pp. 1– 27.
OECD (1991) Cities and New Technologies.
Paris: OECD.
PARKINSON, M. and HARDING, A. (1995) European
cities towards 2000: entrepreneurialism, com-
petition and social exclusion, in: M. RHODES
(Ed.) The Regions and the New Europe: Pat-
terns in Core and Periphery Development,
pp. 53–77. Manchester: Manchester University
Press.
PETERSON, P. E. (1981) City Limits. Chicago, IL:
University of Chicago Press.
POSTONE, M. (1993) Time, Labour and Social
Domination: A Reinterpretation of Marx’s
Critical Theory. Cambridge: Cambridge
University Press.
RUIGROK, W. and TULDER, R. VAN (1996) The
Logic of International Restructuring. London:
Routledge.
SCHUMPETER, J. A. (1934) Theory of Economic
Development: An Inquiry into ProŽ ts, Capital,
Credit, Interest and the Business Cycle.
Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.
STORPER, M. (1997) The city: the centre of
economic re exivity, The Service Industries
Journal, 17, pp. 1– 27.
SUM, N-L. (1995) More than a ‘war of words’:
identity, politics and the struggle for dominance
during the recent ‘political reform’ period in
Hong Kong, Economy and Society, 24, pp. 67–
100.
SUM, N-L. (1996) ‘Greater China’ and global–
regional–local dynamics in the post-Cold War
era, in: I. COOK, M. DOEL, and R. LI (Eds)
Fragmented Asia: Regional Integration and
National Disintegration in PaciŽ c Asia, pp. 53–
74. Aldershot: Avebury.
SUM, N-L. (1999) Rethinking globalization: re-
articulating the spatial scales and temporal
horizons of trans-border spaces, in: K. OLDS, P.
AN ENTREPRENEURIAL CITY IN ACTION 2313
DICKEN, P. E. KELLY ET AL. (Eds) Globalization
and the Asia-PaciŽ c, pp. 129–148. London:
Routledge.
SWYNGEDOUW, E. A. (1997) Neither global nor
local: ‘glocalization’ and the politics of scale,
in: K. COX (Ed.) Spaces of Globalization:
Reasserting the Power of the Local, pp. 137–
166. New York: Guilford.
TAYLOR, M. (1991) Boom with a queue, Far
Eastern Economic Review, 22 August, pp. 48–
49.
TAYLOR, P. J. (1995) World cities and territorial
states, in: P. L. KNOX and P. J. TAYLOR (Eds)
World Cities in a World-system, pp. 48–62.
Cambridge, MA: Cambridge University Press.
VELTZ, P. (1996) Mondialisation de Villes et
Territoires. Paris: Presses Universitaires de
France.
WEBB, D. M. (1999) PaciŽ c Century CyberWork,
5 May (http://webb-site.com/articles/pccyber-
wok.htm).
WONG, P. (1998) Landscape of hegemony and
‘entrepreneureality’: the high technology
industry in Hong Kong. Unpublished PhD
thesis, Lancaster University.

More Related Content

What's hot

TOWARDS A HETERODOX THEORY OF THE SPATIAL ECONOMY
TOWARDS A HETERODOX THEORY OF THE SPATIAL ECONOMYTOWARDS A HETERODOX THEORY OF THE SPATIAL ECONOMY
TOWARDS A HETERODOX THEORY OF THE SPATIAL ECONOMYpkconference
 
Positive contributions entrepreneurs have to the economics of the world
Positive contributions entrepreneurs have to the economics of the worldPositive contributions entrepreneurs have to the economics of the world
Positive contributions entrepreneurs have to the economics of the worldMbasa Mwawembe
 
1. urban economics and its scope
1.  urban economics and its scope1.  urban economics and its scope
1. urban economics and its scopeKokab Manzoor
 
Lurking in the Cities: Urbanization and the Informal Economy
Lurking in the Cities: Urbanization and the Informal Economy Lurking in the Cities: Urbanization and the Informal Economy
Lurking in the Cities: Urbanization and the Informal Economy Dr Lendy Spires
 
Assessment of New Towns Self Sufficiency
Assessment of New Towns Self SufficiencyAssessment of New Towns Self Sufficiency
Assessment of New Towns Self SufficiencyJahanshah Pakzad
 
Christaller's central place theory
Christaller's central place theoryChristaller's central place theory
Christaller's central place theoryNishla fathima
 
Rank size rule and primate city concept
Rank size rule and primate city conceptRank size rule and primate city concept
Rank size rule and primate city conceptTryambakesh Shukla
 
Rethinking the Framework for Production - MTI Future Tense 2012
Rethinking the Framework for Production - MTI Future Tense 2012Rethinking the Framework for Production - MTI Future Tense 2012
Rethinking the Framework for Production - MTI Future Tense 2012Hawyee Auyong
 
Criticism and assumption cristtaler
Criticism and assumption   cristtalerCriticism and assumption   cristtaler
Criticism and assumption cristtalerKaium Chowdhury
 
The Creative Economy in Pernambuco_Sunil_Tankha
The Creative Economy in Pernambuco_Sunil_TankhaThe Creative Economy in Pernambuco_Sunil_Tankha
The Creative Economy in Pernambuco_Sunil_TankhaEdgar Andrade
 
Equitable and social city social entrepreneurs
Equitable and social city social entrepreneursEquitable and social city social entrepreneurs
Equitable and social city social entrepreneursJurgen Hoogendoorn
 
Song_Bingtao
Song_BingtaoSong_Bingtao
Song_Bingtaofinance14
 
Co living insights in the APAC region
Co living insights in the APAC regionCo living insights in the APAC region
Co living insights in the APAC regionJoseba U
 
How massachusetts can become more innovative
How massachusetts can become more innovativeHow massachusetts can become more innovative
How massachusetts can become more innovativeFan Feng
 

What's hot (17)

M mpes-territ stratplan-bmpmarques
M mpes-territ stratplan-bmpmarquesM mpes-territ stratplan-bmpmarques
M mpes-territ stratplan-bmpmarques
 
wwer efter
wwer efterwwer efter
wwer efter
 
TOWARDS A HETERODOX THEORY OF THE SPATIAL ECONOMY
TOWARDS A HETERODOX THEORY OF THE SPATIAL ECONOMYTOWARDS A HETERODOX THEORY OF THE SPATIAL ECONOMY
TOWARDS A HETERODOX THEORY OF THE SPATIAL ECONOMY
 
Positive contributions entrepreneurs have to the economics of the world
Positive contributions entrepreneurs have to the economics of the worldPositive contributions entrepreneurs have to the economics of the world
Positive contributions entrepreneurs have to the economics of the world
 
1. urban economics and its scope
1.  urban economics and its scope1.  urban economics and its scope
1. urban economics and its scope
 
Lurking in the Cities: Urbanization and the Informal Economy
Lurking in the Cities: Urbanization and the Informal Economy Lurking in the Cities: Urbanization and the Informal Economy
Lurking in the Cities: Urbanization and the Informal Economy
 
Assessment of New Towns Self Sufficiency
Assessment of New Towns Self SufficiencyAssessment of New Towns Self Sufficiency
Assessment of New Towns Self Sufficiency
 
Christaller's central place theory
Christaller's central place theoryChristaller's central place theory
Christaller's central place theory
 
Rank size rule and primate city concept
Rank size rule and primate city conceptRank size rule and primate city concept
Rank size rule and primate city concept
 
Rethinking the Framework for Production - MTI Future Tense 2012
Rethinking the Framework for Production - MTI Future Tense 2012Rethinking the Framework for Production - MTI Future Tense 2012
Rethinking the Framework for Production - MTI Future Tense 2012
 
CentralPlaceJF
CentralPlaceJFCentralPlaceJF
CentralPlaceJF
 
Criticism and assumption cristtaler
Criticism and assumption   cristtalerCriticism and assumption   cristtaler
Criticism and assumption cristtaler
 
The Creative Economy in Pernambuco_Sunil_Tankha
The Creative Economy in Pernambuco_Sunil_TankhaThe Creative Economy in Pernambuco_Sunil_Tankha
The Creative Economy in Pernambuco_Sunil_Tankha
 
Equitable and social city social entrepreneurs
Equitable and social city social entrepreneursEquitable and social city social entrepreneurs
Equitable and social city social entrepreneurs
 
Song_Bingtao
Song_BingtaoSong_Bingtao
Song_Bingtao
 
Co living insights in the APAC region
Co living insights in the APAC regionCo living insights in the APAC region
Co living insights in the APAC region
 
How massachusetts can become more innovative
How massachusetts can become more innovativeHow massachusetts can become more innovative
How massachusetts can become more innovative
 

Similar to Cibercity hong kong

Ethnicity And Space In The Global City A New Frontier
Ethnicity And Space In The Global City  A New FrontierEthnicity And Space In The Global City  A New Frontier
Ethnicity And Space In The Global City A New FrontierAlvaroMier
 
2009 The culture and economics of urban public space design public and profes...
2009 The culture and economics of urban public space design public and profes...2009 The culture and economics of urban public space design public and profes...
2009 The culture and economics of urban public space design public and profes...Lee Pugalis
 
Globalization and political economy
Globalization and political economyGlobalization and political economy
Globalization and political economyArghyadeep Saha
 
2012 evolutionary waves of place-shaping pre during and post recession - pu...
2012   evolutionary waves of place-shaping pre during and post recession - pu...2012   evolutionary waves of place-shaping pre during and post recession - pu...
2012 evolutionary waves of place-shaping pre during and post recession - pu...Lee Pugalis
 
Team Finland Future Watch Report, Innovative planning in the U.S., Engaging c...
Team Finland Future Watch Report, Innovative planning in the U.S., Engaging c...Team Finland Future Watch Report, Innovative planning in the U.S., Engaging c...
Team Finland Future Watch Report, Innovative planning in the U.S., Engaging c...Team Finland Future Watch
 
Changing Role Of Planners in UK.docx
Changing Role Of Planners in UK.docxChanging Role Of Planners in UK.docx
Changing Role Of Planners in UK.docxsdfghj21
 
Beyond Smart and Data-Driven City-Regions? Rethinking Stakeholder-Helixes Str...
Beyond Smart and Data-Driven City-Regions? Rethinking Stakeholder-Helixes Str...Beyond Smart and Data-Driven City-Regions? Rethinking Stakeholder-Helixes Str...
Beyond Smart and Data-Driven City-Regions? Rethinking Stakeholder-Helixes Str...Dr Igor Calzada, MBA, FeRSA
 
Spatial Modelling Metropolization Portugal
Spatial Modelling Metropolization PortugalSpatial Modelling Metropolization Portugal
Spatial Modelling Metropolization PortugalCláudio Carneiro
 
The experience of Participatory Budgets in the city of Seville
The experience of  Participatory Budgets  in the city of SevilleThe experience of  Participatory Budgets  in the city of Seville
The experience of Participatory Budgets in the city of SevilleFrancisco Sierra Caballero
 
4 centers-tokyo
4 centers-tokyo4 centers-tokyo
4 centers-tokyoGreg Wass
 
Smart cities as spatial manifestations of 21st century capitalism
Smart cities as spatial manifestations of 21st century capitalismSmart cities as spatial manifestations of 21st century capitalism
Smart cities as spatial manifestations of 21st century capitalismAraz Taeihagh
 
Comparing Smart City-Regional Governance Strategies in Bristol, Glasgow, Barc...
Comparing Smart City-Regional Governance Strategies in Bristol, Glasgow, Barc...Comparing Smart City-Regional Governance Strategies in Bristol, Glasgow, Barc...
Comparing Smart City-Regional Governance Strategies in Bristol, Glasgow, Barc...Dr Igor Calzada, MBA, FeRSA
 
The sustainability of competing urban development models-The myth of the glob...
The sustainability of competing urban development models-The myth of the glob...The sustainability of competing urban development models-The myth of the glob...
The sustainability of competing urban development models-The myth of the glob...Ioana Dumea
 
Developing a conceptual framework
Developing a conceptual frameworkDeveloping a conceptual framework
Developing a conceptual frameworkLAZOVOY
 
Economic Diversification and the Urban Image; Changing the Narrative on Stree...
Economic Diversification and the Urban Image; Changing the Narrative on Stree...Economic Diversification and the Urban Image; Changing the Narrative on Stree...
Economic Diversification and the Urban Image; Changing the Narrative on Stree...Journal of Contemporary Urban Affairs
 

Similar to Cibercity hong kong (20)

Ethnicity And Space In The Global City A New Frontier
Ethnicity And Space In The Global City  A New FrontierEthnicity And Space In The Global City  A New Frontier
Ethnicity And Space In The Global City A New Frontier
 
2009 The culture and economics of urban public space design public and profes...
2009 The culture and economics of urban public space design public and profes...2009 The culture and economics of urban public space design public and profes...
2009 The culture and economics of urban public space design public and profes...
 
Why a city growt
Why a city growtWhy a city growt
Why a city growt
 
Globalization and political economy
Globalization and political economyGlobalization and political economy
Globalization and political economy
 
2012 evolutionary waves of place-shaping pre during and post recession - pu...
2012   evolutionary waves of place-shaping pre during and post recession - pu...2012   evolutionary waves of place-shaping pre during and post recession - pu...
2012 evolutionary waves of place-shaping pre during and post recession - pu...
 
Team Finland Future Watch Report, Innovative planning in the U.S., Engaging c...
Team Finland Future Watch Report, Innovative planning in the U.S., Engaging c...Team Finland Future Watch Report, Innovative planning in the U.S., Engaging c...
Team Finland Future Watch Report, Innovative planning in the U.S., Engaging c...
 
Changing Role Of Planners in UK.docx
Changing Role Of Planners in UK.docxChanging Role Of Planners in UK.docx
Changing Role Of Planners in UK.docx
 
Some Notes about Architecture, Urbanism and Economy
Some Notes about Architecture, Urbanism and EconomySome Notes about Architecture, Urbanism and Economy
Some Notes about Architecture, Urbanism and Economy
 
Beyond Smart and Data-Driven City-Regions? Rethinking Stakeholder-Helixes Str...
Beyond Smart and Data-Driven City-Regions? Rethinking Stakeholder-Helixes Str...Beyond Smart and Data-Driven City-Regions? Rethinking Stakeholder-Helixes Str...
Beyond Smart and Data-Driven City-Regions? Rethinking Stakeholder-Helixes Str...
 
Some Notes about Architecture, Urbanism and Economy
Some Notes about Architecture, Urbanism and EconomySome Notes about Architecture, Urbanism and Economy
Some Notes about Architecture, Urbanism and Economy
 
Spatial Modelling Metropolization Portugal
Spatial Modelling Metropolization PortugalSpatial Modelling Metropolization Portugal
Spatial Modelling Metropolization Portugal
 
The experience of Participatory Budgets in the city of Seville
The experience of  Participatory Budgets  in the city of SevilleThe experience of  Participatory Budgets  in the city of Seville
The experience of Participatory Budgets in the city of Seville
 
4 centers-tokyo
4 centers-tokyo4 centers-tokyo
4 centers-tokyo
 
Smart cities as spatial manifestations of 21st century capitalism
Smart cities as spatial manifestations of 21st century capitalismSmart cities as spatial manifestations of 21st century capitalism
Smart cities as spatial manifestations of 21st century capitalism
 
AcademicDossierAdriano
AcademicDossierAdrianoAcademicDossierAdriano
AcademicDossierAdriano
 
Comparing Smart City-Regional Governance Strategies in Bristol, Glasgow, Barc...
Comparing Smart City-Regional Governance Strategies in Bristol, Glasgow, Barc...Comparing Smart City-Regional Governance Strategies in Bristol, Glasgow, Barc...
Comparing Smart City-Regional Governance Strategies in Bristol, Glasgow, Barc...
 
parking master plan
parking master planparking master plan
parking master plan
 
The sustainability of competing urban development models-The myth of the glob...
The sustainability of competing urban development models-The myth of the glob...The sustainability of competing urban development models-The myth of the glob...
The sustainability of competing urban development models-The myth of the glob...
 
Developing a conceptual framework
Developing a conceptual frameworkDeveloping a conceptual framework
Developing a conceptual framework
 
Economic Diversification and the Urban Image; Changing the Narrative on Stree...
Economic Diversification and the Urban Image; Changing the Narrative on Stree...Economic Diversification and the Urban Image; Changing the Narrative on Stree...
Economic Diversification and the Urban Image; Changing the Narrative on Stree...
 

Recently uploaded

Call Girls In Panjim North Goa 9971646499 Genuine Service
Call Girls In Panjim North Goa 9971646499 Genuine ServiceCall Girls In Panjim North Goa 9971646499 Genuine Service
Call Girls In Panjim North Goa 9971646499 Genuine Serviceritikaroy0888
 
BEST ✨ Call Girls In Indirapuram Ghaziabad ✔️ 9871031762 ✔️ Escorts Service...
BEST ✨ Call Girls In  Indirapuram Ghaziabad  ✔️ 9871031762 ✔️ Escorts Service...BEST ✨ Call Girls In  Indirapuram Ghaziabad  ✔️ 9871031762 ✔️ Escorts Service...
BEST ✨ Call Girls In Indirapuram Ghaziabad ✔️ 9871031762 ✔️ Escorts Service...noida100girls
 
Regression analysis: Simple Linear Regression Multiple Linear Regression
Regression analysis:  Simple Linear Regression Multiple Linear RegressionRegression analysis:  Simple Linear Regression Multiple Linear Regression
Regression analysis: Simple Linear Regression Multiple Linear RegressionRavindra Nath Shukla
 
A DAY IN THE LIFE OF A SALESMAN / WOMAN
A DAY IN THE LIFE OF A  SALESMAN / WOMANA DAY IN THE LIFE OF A  SALESMAN / WOMAN
A DAY IN THE LIFE OF A SALESMAN / WOMANIlamathiKannappan
 
Tech Startup Growth Hacking 101 - Basics on Growth Marketing
Tech Startup Growth Hacking 101  - Basics on Growth MarketingTech Startup Growth Hacking 101  - Basics on Growth Marketing
Tech Startup Growth Hacking 101 - Basics on Growth MarketingShawn Pang
 
Catalogue ONG NƯỚC uPVC - HDPE DE NHAT.pdf
Catalogue ONG NƯỚC uPVC - HDPE DE NHAT.pdfCatalogue ONG NƯỚC uPVC - HDPE DE NHAT.pdf
Catalogue ONG NƯỚC uPVC - HDPE DE NHAT.pdfOrient Homes
 
The Coffee Bean & Tea Leaf(CBTL), Business strategy case study
The Coffee Bean & Tea Leaf(CBTL), Business strategy case studyThe Coffee Bean & Tea Leaf(CBTL), Business strategy case study
The Coffee Bean & Tea Leaf(CBTL), Business strategy case studyEthan lee
 
GD Birla and his contribution in management
GD Birla and his contribution in managementGD Birla and his contribution in management
GD Birla and his contribution in managementchhavia330
 
Pharma Works Profile of Karan Communications
Pharma Works Profile of Karan CommunicationsPharma Works Profile of Karan Communications
Pharma Works Profile of Karan Communicationskarancommunications
 
VIP Call Girls Pune Kirti 8617697112 Independent Escort Service Pune
VIP Call Girls Pune Kirti 8617697112 Independent Escort Service PuneVIP Call Girls Pune Kirti 8617697112 Independent Escort Service Pune
VIP Call Girls Pune Kirti 8617697112 Independent Escort Service PuneCall girls in Ahmedabad High profile
 
Call Girls Navi Mumbai Just Call 9907093804 Top Class Call Girl Service Avail...
Call Girls Navi Mumbai Just Call 9907093804 Top Class Call Girl Service Avail...Call Girls Navi Mumbai Just Call 9907093804 Top Class Call Girl Service Avail...
Call Girls Navi Mumbai Just Call 9907093804 Top Class Call Girl Service Avail...Dipal Arora
 
Ensure the security of your HCL environment by applying the Zero Trust princi...
Ensure the security of your HCL environment by applying the Zero Trust princi...Ensure the security of your HCL environment by applying the Zero Trust princi...
Ensure the security of your HCL environment by applying the Zero Trust princi...Roland Driesen
 
VIP Kolkata Call Girl Howrah 👉 8250192130 Available With Room
VIP Kolkata Call Girl Howrah 👉 8250192130  Available With RoomVIP Kolkata Call Girl Howrah 👉 8250192130  Available With Room
VIP Kolkata Call Girl Howrah 👉 8250192130 Available With Roomdivyansh0kumar0
 
Progress Report - Oracle Database Analyst Summit
Progress  Report - Oracle Database Analyst SummitProgress  Report - Oracle Database Analyst Summit
Progress Report - Oracle Database Analyst SummitHolger Mueller
 
Sales & Marketing Alignment: How to Synergize for Success
Sales & Marketing Alignment: How to Synergize for SuccessSales & Marketing Alignment: How to Synergize for Success
Sales & Marketing Alignment: How to Synergize for SuccessAggregage
 
Socio-economic-Impact-of-business-consumers-suppliers-and.pptx
Socio-economic-Impact-of-business-consumers-suppliers-and.pptxSocio-economic-Impact-of-business-consumers-suppliers-and.pptx
Socio-economic-Impact-of-business-consumers-suppliers-and.pptxtrishalcan8
 
Catalogue ONG NUOC PPR DE NHAT .pdf
Catalogue ONG NUOC PPR DE NHAT      .pdfCatalogue ONG NUOC PPR DE NHAT      .pdf
Catalogue ONG NUOC PPR DE NHAT .pdfOrient Homes
 

Recently uploaded (20)

Call Girls In Panjim North Goa 9971646499 Genuine Service
Call Girls In Panjim North Goa 9971646499 Genuine ServiceCall Girls In Panjim North Goa 9971646499 Genuine Service
Call Girls In Panjim North Goa 9971646499 Genuine Service
 
BEST ✨ Call Girls In Indirapuram Ghaziabad ✔️ 9871031762 ✔️ Escorts Service...
BEST ✨ Call Girls In  Indirapuram Ghaziabad  ✔️ 9871031762 ✔️ Escorts Service...BEST ✨ Call Girls In  Indirapuram Ghaziabad  ✔️ 9871031762 ✔️ Escorts Service...
BEST ✨ Call Girls In Indirapuram Ghaziabad ✔️ 9871031762 ✔️ Escorts Service...
 
Regression analysis: Simple Linear Regression Multiple Linear Regression
Regression analysis:  Simple Linear Regression Multiple Linear RegressionRegression analysis:  Simple Linear Regression Multiple Linear Regression
Regression analysis: Simple Linear Regression Multiple Linear Regression
 
A DAY IN THE LIFE OF A SALESMAN / WOMAN
A DAY IN THE LIFE OF A  SALESMAN / WOMANA DAY IN THE LIFE OF A  SALESMAN / WOMAN
A DAY IN THE LIFE OF A SALESMAN / WOMAN
 
Tech Startup Growth Hacking 101 - Basics on Growth Marketing
Tech Startup Growth Hacking 101  - Basics on Growth MarketingTech Startup Growth Hacking 101  - Basics on Growth Marketing
Tech Startup Growth Hacking 101 - Basics on Growth Marketing
 
Catalogue ONG NƯỚC uPVC - HDPE DE NHAT.pdf
Catalogue ONG NƯỚC uPVC - HDPE DE NHAT.pdfCatalogue ONG NƯỚC uPVC - HDPE DE NHAT.pdf
Catalogue ONG NƯỚC uPVC - HDPE DE NHAT.pdf
 
The Coffee Bean & Tea Leaf(CBTL), Business strategy case study
The Coffee Bean & Tea Leaf(CBTL), Business strategy case studyThe Coffee Bean & Tea Leaf(CBTL), Business strategy case study
The Coffee Bean & Tea Leaf(CBTL), Business strategy case study
 
Best Practices for Implementing an External Recruiting Partnership
Best Practices for Implementing an External Recruiting PartnershipBest Practices for Implementing an External Recruiting Partnership
Best Practices for Implementing an External Recruiting Partnership
 
GD Birla and his contribution in management
GD Birla and his contribution in managementGD Birla and his contribution in management
GD Birla and his contribution in management
 
Pharma Works Profile of Karan Communications
Pharma Works Profile of Karan CommunicationsPharma Works Profile of Karan Communications
Pharma Works Profile of Karan Communications
 
VIP Call Girls Pune Kirti 8617697112 Independent Escort Service Pune
VIP Call Girls Pune Kirti 8617697112 Independent Escort Service PuneVIP Call Girls Pune Kirti 8617697112 Independent Escort Service Pune
VIP Call Girls Pune Kirti 8617697112 Independent Escort Service Pune
 
Call Girls Navi Mumbai Just Call 9907093804 Top Class Call Girl Service Avail...
Call Girls Navi Mumbai Just Call 9907093804 Top Class Call Girl Service Avail...Call Girls Navi Mumbai Just Call 9907093804 Top Class Call Girl Service Avail...
Call Girls Navi Mumbai Just Call 9907093804 Top Class Call Girl Service Avail...
 
Ensure the security of your HCL environment by applying the Zero Trust princi...
Ensure the security of your HCL environment by applying the Zero Trust princi...Ensure the security of your HCL environment by applying the Zero Trust princi...
Ensure the security of your HCL environment by applying the Zero Trust princi...
 
VIP Kolkata Call Girl Howrah 👉 8250192130 Available With Room
VIP Kolkata Call Girl Howrah 👉 8250192130  Available With RoomVIP Kolkata Call Girl Howrah 👉 8250192130  Available With Room
VIP Kolkata Call Girl Howrah 👉 8250192130 Available With Room
 
Progress Report - Oracle Database Analyst Summit
Progress  Report - Oracle Database Analyst SummitProgress  Report - Oracle Database Analyst Summit
Progress Report - Oracle Database Analyst Summit
 
Forklift Operations: Safety through Cartoons
Forklift Operations: Safety through CartoonsForklift Operations: Safety through Cartoons
Forklift Operations: Safety through Cartoons
 
Sales & Marketing Alignment: How to Synergize for Success
Sales & Marketing Alignment: How to Synergize for SuccessSales & Marketing Alignment: How to Synergize for Success
Sales & Marketing Alignment: How to Synergize for Success
 
Socio-economic-Impact-of-business-consumers-suppliers-and.pptx
Socio-economic-Impact-of-business-consumers-suppliers-and.pptxSocio-economic-Impact-of-business-consumers-suppliers-and.pptx
Socio-economic-Impact-of-business-consumers-suppliers-and.pptx
 
Nepali Escort Girl Kakori \ 9548273370 Indian Call Girls Service Lucknow ₹,9517
Nepali Escort Girl Kakori \ 9548273370 Indian Call Girls Service Lucknow ₹,9517Nepali Escort Girl Kakori \ 9548273370 Indian Call Girls Service Lucknow ₹,9517
Nepali Escort Girl Kakori \ 9548273370 Indian Call Girls Service Lucknow ₹,9517
 
Catalogue ONG NUOC PPR DE NHAT .pdf
Catalogue ONG NUOC PPR DE NHAT      .pdfCatalogue ONG NUOC PPR DE NHAT      .pdf
Catalogue ONG NUOC PPR DE NHAT .pdf
 

Cibercity hong kong

  • 1. Urban Studies, Vol. 37, No. 12, 2287– 2313, 2000 An Entrepreneurial City in Action: Hong Kong’s Emerging Strategies in and for (Inter)Urban Competition Bob Jessop and Ngai-Ling Sum [Paper Žrst received, September 1999; in Ž nal form, April 2000] Summary. The paper applies a Schumpeterian analysis of entrepreneurial cities to Hong Kong. It argues that the concept of entrepreneurship can be applied to cities as strategic actors, identiŽ es various objects of urban entrepreneurship, and refers to the important role of entrepreneurial discourses, narratives and self-images. Despite its laissez-faire reputation, Hong Kong has a long history of urban entrepreneurship, but its strategies have been adapted to changing circumstances—most recently with its key role in an emerging cross-border region (Greater China) and its favourable insertion into the global economy. This has prompted a debate over the most appropriate strategies for Hong Kong, notably regarding the respective futures of manufacturing, services and the virtual economy. The concept of ‘glurbanisation’ as one form of the more general phenomenon of ‘glocalisation’ is introduced to illuminate these issues. The paper concludes by noting the increased importance of ‘Siliconisation’ as an accumulation strategy in east Asia. There is widespread interest among policy- makers and observers alike in the en- trepreneurial city. It is less obvious what exactly being an entrepreneurial city in- volves. To help resolve this conundrum, our paper Ž rst provides a Schumpeterian analysis of the entrepreneurial city and then illustrates it with the Hong Kong case. We Ž rst offer a three-part deŽ nition of the entrepreneurial city in capitalist societies. This relates urban entrepreneurship to changing forms of com- petitiveness, changing strategies to promote interurban competitiveness in both the econ- omic and extra-economic Ž elds and en- trepreneurial discourses, narratives and self-images. Schumpeter identiŽ ed Ž ve ways in which entrepreneurs innovate in normal economic activities; our analysis identiŽ es parallels in urban entrepreneurialism. We then critically consider how far such an analysis is valid given the differences be- tween the types of actor involved and the objects of their innovation—answering afŽ rmatively in both respects and suggesting the conditions in which cities can be de- scribed as strategic actors with entrepreneu- rial ambitions. This theoretical analysis is further reŽ ned and justiŽ ed from recent de- velopments in Hong Kong and east Asia. Conventionally regarded as a paradigm case of laissez-faire and ofŽ cially described in the decades before 1997 as practising ‘positive Bob Jessop is in the Department of Sociology, Lancaster University, Lancaster, LA1 4YL, UK. Fax: 01524 594256. E-mail: b.jessop@lancaster.ac.uk. Ngai-Ling Sum is with the International Centre for Labour Studies, Williamson Building, University of Manchester, Oxford Road, Manchester, M13 9PL, UK. E-mail: Ngai-Ling.Sum@man.ac.uk. The authors have have beneŽ ted from discussions with Neil Brenner, Carolyn Cartier, Anne Haila, Gordon McLeod, Jamie Peck and Ngai Pun. The usual disclaimers apply. 0042-0980 Print/1360-063X On-line/00/122287-27 Ó 2000 The Editors of Urban Studies DOI: 10.1080/0042098002 0002814
  • 2. BOB JESSOP AND NGAI-LING SUM 2288 non-intervention’, Hong Kong actually has a long history of urban entrepreneurship based on public–private partnerships. But its strate- gies have been modiŽ ed as the economic and political environments have changed. Our contribution is particularly concerned with the recent period, when Hong Kong’s en- trepreneurial city strategies have been devel- oped against the background of an emerging cross-border regional space (Greater China) and its favourable insertion into the global circuits of capital. In this context we intro- duce the concept of ‘glurbanisation’ as one form of the more general phenomenon of ‘glocalisation’ and show how it can be used to illuminate current entrepreneurial city strategies in east Asia. Thus the second part of the paper de- scribes how, between the 1970s and the early 1990s, Hong Kong responded in two ways to the growing relocation of its local manufac- turing activities to the mainland. It became the key node in co-ordinating ‘sub-contract- ing management’ for the ‘Greater China’ region; and, in addition, its increasingly in- ternationalised Ž nancial and producer ser- vices sectors expanded to Ž ll the gaps created by the ‘hollowing-out’ of Hong Kong’s local manufacturing base. Hong Kong’s continu- ing rise from the mid 1980s onwards as a regional Ž nancial centre provided ample funds for further expansion by local property capital. These structural shifts strengthened the position of Ž nance and property capital in the local power bloc. As property became an increasingly important sphere of capital ac- cumulation, industrial and commercial capi- tals worried about the lack of high-tech investment and the rising cost of all econ- omic activities in Hong Kong. This was re ected in the development of two major alternative urban strategic orientations or- ganised around the competing interests of industry and producer services and con- cerned in their different ways with problems of interscalar articulation and chronotopic governance. Mobilising support for, and pur- suing, these strategies was complicated in the mid 1990s by the primacy of political calcu- lations around the transition (on this period, see Sum, 1995). Moreover, shortly after the 1997 return of Hong Kong to the mainland, the outbreak of the Asian crisis initially dis- oriented and disrupted these strategies. When the crisis stabilised in early 1999, however, the competing visions took on a new life and generated even more explicit and re exive urban entrepreneurialism. In particular, since urban economic growth is locked into a prop- erty-related path, the government is now seeking to build a new urban bloc.1 This would consolidate real estate, commercial and technological interests around new en- trepreneurial projects such as a science park, cyberport and Chinese-medicine port.2 Such projects serve to unify different interests in Hong Kong and are also mediating the emergence of a global–regional–national bloc of economic actors involved in infor- mation and communication technologies and services—in the case of the cyberport, for example, these include Microsoft, Acer from Taiwan and IT Ž rms from Hong Kong and China. These entrepreneurial projects are by no means unique to Hong Kong and, indeed, they are facing competition from similar projects in Singapore, Kuala Lumpur and Beijing. 1. What is an Entrepreneurial City? It might be argued that entrepreneurial cities have existed for centuries, if not millennia and, in terms of institutional structures and strategies supporting economic innovation, this could well be true (see, for example, Hall, 1998; Braudel, 1984; Jacobs, 1984; Taylor, 1995). But this argument views cities as engines of wealth creation regardless of the speciŽ c form in which this occurs—and so fails to capture what is novel about the role of entrepreneurial cities in capital accu- mulation. (On the distinction between wealth and capital, see Postone, 1993). The litera- ture on urban growth machines does combine a focus on wealth creation with interest in the dynamics of property capital and in this re- gard has some similarities with our own ap- proach. But urban growth machine studies have been more concerned with local devel-
  • 3. AN ENTREPRENEURIAL CITY IN ACTION 2289 opmental strategies and the political alliances that support them than with issues of inter- scalar articulation and they have also exam- ined a restricted range of the entrepreneurial strategies that we identify below. In addition, our own approach highlights the importance of entrepreneurial discourse and narratives and is concerned with the periodisation of strategies—something that is neglected in the urban growth machine literature (for com- mentaries on the latter, see Jonas and Wilson, 1999). In particular, we propose three deŽ ning features of entrepreneurial cities: —An entrepreneurial city pursues innovative strategies intended to maintain or enhance its economic competitiveness vis-à-vis other cities and economic spaces. —These strategies are real and re exive. They are not ‘as if’ strategies, but are more or less explicitly formulated and pursued in an active, entrepreneurial fashion. —The promoters of entrepreneurial cities adopt an entrepreneurial discourse, narrate their cities as entrepreneurial and market them as entrepreneurial. The Ž rst and second criteria distinguish cities that happen for whatever reason(s) to per- form well economically from those that are entrepreneurial. For not all cities that per- form well are entrepreneurial; and not all entrepreneurial cities perform well. Adopting the second criterion directs attention to the conditions under which cities can be said to act in a relatively uniŽ ed and strategic man- ner and/or in which speciŽ c social forces are able to deŽ ne the interests of the city and be seen to act for and on behalf of the latter. Only where explicit strategies are pursued can we talk of an entrepreneurial city. The third criterion is useful in distinguishing the entrepreneurial city from non-entrepreneurial urban regimes. Urban regimes and urban blocs pursue many different kinds of econ- omic, political and socio-cultural strategy— for example, religious centre, dream factory, imperial capital, modernist utopia, municipal socialism or tourist centre (Hall, 1998). Only some adopt an explicitly entrepreneu- rial self-identity as well as an entrepreneurial strategy. Our approach to the Ž rst and second cri- teria for identifying entrepreneurial cities is in uenced by Schumpeter, an emblematic thinker for contemporary capitalism, who deŽ ned entrepreneurship as the creation of opportunities for surplus proŽ t through ‘new combinations’ or innovation (Schumpeter, 1934); and by Harvey, an arguably more controversial thinker on post-modern capital- ism, who has presented some in uential ideas on the shift from urban managerialism to urban entrepreneurialism (Harvey, 1989). Their work is very useful in deŽ ning the nature of entrepreneurial strategies oriented to enhancing the competitiveness of cities and regions. Schumpeter listed several ways in which innovation can occur: (1) The introduction of a new good—that is one with which consumers are not yet familiar—or a new quality of a good. (2) The introduction of a new method of pro- duction, that is one not yet tested by ex- perience in the branch of manufacture concerned, which need by no means be founded upon a discovery scientiŽ cally new, and can also exist in a new way of handling a commodity commercially. (3) The opening of a new market, that is a market into which the particular branch of manufacture of the country in question has not previously entered, whether or not this market has existed before. (4) The con- quest of a new source of supply of raw materials or half-manufactured goods, again irrespective of whether this source already exists or whether it has Ž rst to be created. (5) The carrying out of the new organization of any industry, like the cre- ation of a monopoly position (for example through trustiŽ cation) or the breaking up of a monopoly position (Lim, 1990, p. 215; summarising Schumpeter, 1934, pp. 129–135). Schumpeter was concerned with entrepreneu- rial innovation in the supply of commodities by Ž rms as economic actors. One might ob-
  • 4. BOB JESSOP AND NGAI-LING SUM 2290 ject that cities are not Ž rms and do not produce commodities.3 But a Schumpeterian interpretation of cities focuses on cities’ overall capacities to promote innovation in urban form and also adopts a broader account of competition that includes extra-economic as well as economic factors. Thus cities can be entrepreneurial not only in regard to com- modities and Ž ctitious commodities, but also in regard to economically relevant factors that are not monetised and/or do not enter directly into exchange relations. The chang- ing forms of competition are especially im- portant here because extra-economic factors have become more central to economic com- petitiveness (see Veltz, 1996). In these terms, we can identify Ž ve analyt- ically distinct (but perhaps empirically over- lapping) Ž elds in which directly economic and/or economically relevant innovation can occur in relation to urban form and functions. These Ž elds comprise: (1) The introduction of new types of urban place or space for producing, servicing, working, consuming, living, etc. Recent examples include technopoles, intelligent cities, cross-border cities, multicultural cities and cities organised around inte- grated transport and sustainable develop- ment. (2) New methods of space or place pro- duction to create location-speciŽ c advan- tages for producing goods/services or other urban activities. Recent examples include the installation of new physical, social and cybernetic infrastructures, the promotion of scale and agglomeration economies, regulatory undercutting or creating new forms of labour market re- lation. (3) Opening new markets—whether by place marketing speciŽ c cities in new areas and/or modifying the spatial div- ision of consumption through enhancing the quality of life for residents, com- muters or visitors (for example, culture, entertainment, spectacles, new city- scapes, gay quarters, gentriŽ cation). (4) Finding new sources of supply to en- hance competitive advantages. Examples include new sources or patterns of immi- gration, changing the cultural mix of cit- ies, Ž nding new sources of funding from the central state (or, in the EU, European funds), attracting inward investment or reskilling the workforce. (5) ReŽ guring or redeŽ ning the urban hier- archy and/or altering the place of a given city within it. Examples include the de- velopment of a world or global city pos- ition, regional gateways, hubs, cross-border regions and ‘virtual re- gions’ based on interregional co-oper- ation among non-contiguous spaces. Each of these forms of activity can be seen as innovative or entrepreneurial in the Schum- peterian sense and each of their objects also provides a possible basis for explicit urban strategies. This does not mean, of course, that each and every new place or space, new method of space or place production, new market, new source of supply or new urban hierarchy results directly from successful re- alisation of explicit entrepreneurial strate- gies. This qualiŽ cation is required not only because highly original innovations can soon become routinised through ‘swarming’ ef- fects (for example, science parks, technopoles or waterfront regeneration re- development schemes) but also because new phenomena can emerge from the impersonal play of the market mechanism rather than explicitly formulated entrepreneurial or managerial strategies. Indeed, whilst Ž rst movers often introduce innovations in a more spontaneous, less re ective way, it is follow- ers who tend to be more explicitly en- trepreneurial. An interesting example relevant to our concerns below is the rise of Silicon Valley as an innovative milieu com- pared with attempts to replicate its success elsewhere. Regarding the second criterion, cities can be deŽ ned as ‘entrepreneurial’ actors only if they are meaningful units of competition and able to pursue competitive strategies. Other- wise they could at best be said to be re- presenting or marketing themselves as such
  • 5. AN ENTREPRENEURIAL CITY IN ACTION 2291 through entrepreneurial narratives and/or to be serving as sites more or less favourable to entrepreneurial initiatives emanating from elsewhere. Nonetheless, Cox and Mair sug- gest that If people interpret localized social struc- tures in explicitly territorial terms, come to view their interests and identities as ‘lo- cal’, and then act upon that view by mobi- lizing locally deŽ ned organizations to further their interests in a manner that would not be possible were they to act separately, then it seems eminently reason- able to talk about ‘locality as agent’ (Cox and Mair, 1991, p. 198). These conditions would also apply (without being sufŽ cient) to the mobilisation of di- verse social forces and organisational capac- ities around common entrepreneurial projects. Key elements here would include: the discursive constitution of economic paradigms, identities and modes of calcu- lation that justify claims about an ‘imagined community of entrepreneurial interest’ and its associated collective project, the nature and competencies of the actors (not necess- arily local or locally dependent) who are mobilised behind the entrepreneurial strat- egy, the interpersonal, organisational and (in- ter)organisational mechanisms through which such forces are mobilised and given coherence, and the manner in which these mechanisms are embedded in broader social arrangements so that the capacities of the city (or localised social structure) are in some sense collective and thus irreducible to those of individual actors resident or active therein. In considering how entrepreneurial cities can acquire coherence as collective social forces, we might start with political struc- tures and city politicians. In this context, for example, Clarke and Gaile (1998, p. 13) note that entrepreneurial strategies are more likely in US cities with strong mayoral leadership (and, for similar arguments about Europe, see Harding, 1995; Parkinson and Harding, 1995; and Le Galès and Harding, 1998). The roles of the Tung Chee-Hwa, the Chief Executive of Hong Kong, or Goh Chok Tong, Prime Minister of Singapore, provide clear parallels to such mayoral leadership. New Labour’s promotion of city mayors in Britain, beginning in 2000 with London, also represents a move in the direction of creating conditions for more effective mobilisation behind urban entrepreneurial projects. But we must look beyond city dignitaries to a wider range of actors who might be mo- bilised behind a collective project and to the institutional factors that might help to con- solidate their support. Such actors can in- clude branches of the local, central and, where relevant, supranational state; quangos and hived-off state agencies; political parties; Ž rms; consultancies; trade associations and chambers of commerce; employers’ organi- sations; business roundtables; trades unions; trades councils; citizens’ and community groups; voluntary-sector organisations; pub- lic–private partnerships; local educational and religious institutions; social movements; and diasporic communities. In this sense, the capacity to pursue entrepreneurial strategies and the sort of strategies that are likely to be pursued will clearly depend on state institu- tional and/or territorial structures as well as on broader economic, political and socio- cultural factors. More speciŽ cally, the solid- ity of such projects will depend on their interpersonal, interorganisational and institu- tional embeddedness (hence the existence not only of partnerships but networks of partner- ships structured both horizontally and verti- cally) as well as their feasibility in the light of existing structural constraints and horizons of action. The ability to engage in collective action is linked to capacities for re exion and self- observation and the transformation of what Lipietz calls ‘space-in-itself’ into ‘space-for- itself’. This occurs through the development of a ‘regional armature’ (or regional state apparatus) organised around an urban or re- gional bloc (Lipietz, 1985/1994). Indeed, re exivity has become more important in tandem with the emergence of new forms of uncertainty and risk as market forces and the extra-economic environment of economic ac- tion become more turbulent, more in uenced
  • 6. BOB JESSOP AND NGAI-LING SUM 2292 by the strategic calculation of other actors and more open to in uence on a wide range of spatial scales. These changes privilege forms of urban organisation that enable econ- omic actors to share risks and cope with uncertainty through dense social and institu- tional networks (Storper, 1997; Veltz, 1996). This is why a well-established regional arma- ture is useful. Moreover, because the dy- namic competitive advantages that derive from innovation are likely to be competed away as other economic actors adopt them, it is essential to sustain the economic and ex- tra-economic capacities for ‘permanent inno- vation’. This typically requires a degree of (self-)re exivity that is absent in weakly competitive entrepreneurial cities and/or those that merely engage in boosterism or city marketing. The third criterion appears more straight- forward. For it requires that the promoters of entrepreneurial cities adopt an entrepreneu- rial discourse, narrate their cities as en- trepreneurial and market them as entrepreneurial. This involves the articulation of diverse economic, political and socio- cultural narratives and complementary non- narrative discourses to contextualise and reinforce calls for entrepreneurial action. These narratives often seek to give meaning to current problems by construing them in terms of past failures and future possibilities. In the case of entrepreneurial cities, such narratives typically refer to (actual or poten- tial) losses of competitiveness and the imper- atives and opportunities to restore it in one way or another. This is typically deemed to require decisive changes in the purposes, or- ganisation and delivery of economic strate- gies that are focused on the local, urban or regional levels and infused with some kind of entrepreneurial spirit. Such calls involve the portrayal of the local, urban or regional econ- omy as a distinctive object (of analysis, regu- lation, governance, conquest and/or other practices) with deŽ nite boundaries,4 econ- omic and extra-economic conditions of exist- ence, typical economic agents and extra-economic stakeholders, and an overall dynamic (see Barnes and Ledubur, 1991; Daly, 1993). And they also seek to get social forces on various scales (not just local actors) to identity their interests with the promotion of this (imagined) local, urban or regional economy and the economic and extra- economic conditions presented as necessary to its future success. Where this strategy involves explicit reference to entrepreneurial narratives, strategies and self-identities, then the third criterion for an entrepreneurial city is also satisŽ ed. It is worth noting here that the scope for urban entrepreneurialism has grown in tandem with the expansion of discourses about competitiveness and potential means of enhancing it. In particular, there has been a shift from simple Ricardian concepts of com- petitiveness, based on the relative abundance and relative cost of different factors of pro- duction, to a concern with complex forms of structural or systemic competitiveness. These involve not only socially embedded econ- omic relations (as well as disembedded fac- tors of production), but also extra-economic phenomena, such as education, public– private partnerships, industry–Ž nance rela- tions, state forms, intellectual property regimes, enterprise culture and so on (on structural competitiveness, see Chesnais, 1986; on systemic competitiveness, Messner, 1996). We will illustrate these arguments below (see also Jessop, 1997 and 1999). 2. Interscalar Strategies Cities engage in different kinds of interscalar strategy. Even if they do not act directly as economic entrepreneurs producing commodi- ties (for example, as sponsors of property-led development, tourist spectacles, etc.), cities may still promote an entrepreneurial environ- ment on a range of scales that might help to sustain local growth and make the best use of any opportunities to promote entrepreneur- ship and/or market their places/spaces. In this regard, several strategies can be identiŽ ed. These differ in at least three respects: their respective concepts and discourses of com- petitiveness, the spatial and scalar horizons over which they are meant to operate and
  • 7. AN ENTREPRENEURIAL CITY IN ACTION 2293 their association with different local contexts and positions in prevailing urban hierarchies. What they share is an important role for urban or metropolitan authorities in their overall framing and promulgation. In this sense, for all the talk of the crisis of the state (at whatever level), public authorities still appear to have a major role in organising entrepreneurial policies for the city (includ- ing inner cities and metropolitan regions), re ecting on them and narrating such poli- cies in entrepreneurial terms. A common neo-liberal strategy is con- cerned to attract inward investment and/or to retain extant investment through a Ricardian cost-cutting and deregulatory strategy (Leicht and Jenkins, 1994). This is associated with a static comparative advantage approach to competitiveness, an indifference to scalar articulation and a weak rank in urban hier- archies. A broadly similar but more neo- statist strategy occurs where urban authorities seek resources from higher tiers of government and, perhaps, deploy these to lever additional private investment. Overall, these strategies involve weak forms of com- petition that are unlikely to be sustainable in the long term and they also pose an awkward dilemma over the trade-off between main- taining local autonomy and accepting re- sources that come with restrictive strings attached. Another broad set of strategies, linked to neo-corporatist and neo-statist as well as neo-liberal approaches, involves pursuing some form of structured coherence across scales by building favourable linkages to the wider economy. Such strategies are usually based on a dynamic comparative advantage approach to competitiveness—often linked in turn to notions of structural and/or systemic competitiveness (see above)—and a strong concern with interscalar articulation. More- over, depending on cities’ position in various urban hierarchies or networks, they can cre- ate weaker or stronger forms of competition. In this regard, there are three possible strate- gies (by no means mutually exclusive, let alone exhaustive) that are linked to differ- ences in the preferred form of scalar articula- tion. The Ž rst option is to build horizontal linkages on the same scale (for example, cross-border regions, translocal alliances and ‘virtual regions’ linking non-contiguous locales with shared or complementary inter- ests—such as the European ‘Four Motors’ regions). These horizontal strategies often build on common territorial interests and identities and exploit complementary or joint resources and capacities. Bodies on higher tiers or scales may also promote them— witness the case of the European Union. The second option is to pursue structured comple- mentarities based on a scalar division of labour in an integrated, vertically nested set of scales. This strategy typically involves promoting economic development (on what- ever scale) by exploiting growth dynamics at progressively ascending spatial scales from the local through the regional and the na- tional to the supranational or global. This strategy may be promoted from above and/or may emerge from below. It is re ected dis- cursively in attempts “to position places cen- trally on ‘stages’ of various spatial scales: regional, national, international, global” (Hall and Hubbard, 1996, pp. 163–164). The third option involves building what one might call ‘transversal’ linkages—i.e. by- passing one or more immediately neighbour- ing scale(s) to seek closer integration with processes on various other scales. This can occur in cases such as export-processing zones, free ports or regional gateways where the links to an immediate hinterland or even the national economy are less important than the connection between local and suprana- tional scales. One relatively novel form of interurban competition is ‘glurbanisation’. We have coined this term to distinguish urban from Ž rm-level strategies within the broader con- cept of ‘glocalisation’, which has lost its original precision as it has become the vogue word for all kinds of multiscalar strategies with at least some global aspect. As such it clearly differs from the initial usage of glo- calisation to distinguish the strategy of global localisation pursued by Japanese Ž rms from the strategy of globalisation favoured by
  • 8. BOB JESSOP AND NGAI-LING SUM 2294 many US multinationals.5 In this context, whereas globalisation is oriented to building a worldwide intraŽ rm division of labour with production oriented to world markets and standard tastes, glocalisation is concerned with establishing a geographically concen- trated interŽ rm division of labour in the three major trading blocs (Ruigrok and van Tulder, 1996, p. 180).6 These two contrasting glo- bally oriented strategies can be distinguished from export-oriented domestic production with decentralised marketing; multidomestic production based on establishing foreign pro- duction on a country-by-country basis; screw- driver assembly in one or more domestic economies based on imported components; macroregional divisions of labour within tri- ads; and diadic division of labour strategies oriented to relatively autonomous operations in two macroregions (Ruigrok and van Tul- der, 1996, pp. 181–182). No doubt further strategies could be added that are oriented to plurispatial and multiscalar operations across different national economies. But the com- mon feature of all these strategies is that they are the strategies of potentially mobile Ž rms and thus distinct from the multiscalar strate- gies of cities or other immobile economic units. This suggests that glocalisation will have very different meanings for mobile and immobile economic units—let alone for pol- itical as opposed to economic units. ‘Glocalisation’ has also been used to de- scribe deterritorialisation and reterritorialisa- tion strategies by political units (see initially the work of Swyngedouw, 1997, later Bren- ner, 1997–99). But this is the other side of the contradiction of mobility–immobility in capi- tal accumulation and has a very different dynamic. We suggest that it is more sensible to differentiate strategies on the immobile territorial side as well as on the mobile deter- ritorialising or even aterritorial (i.e. cyber-) side of the accumulation of capital. Failure to do so leads to the conceptual morass of a ‘glocalisation’ concept that simply refers to any and all forms of global–local interaction. The problems involved here are well- illustrated in Brenner’s otherwise excellent work on ‘glocal’ states and ‘glocal’ cities. Brenner relates his work to Lefebvre’s notion of trial by space. This implies that the viability of all strategies of capital accumulation, modes of state regulation and forms of socio-political mobilization has come to depend crucially upon the ability to produce, appropriate, organise, restructure and control social space (Bren- ner, 1997a, p. 1). In this context, Brenner uses ‘glocal’ and its cognates, ‘glocally oriented’ and ‘glocalisa- tion’, to refer to at least four different phe- nomena: (1) The impact of the after-Fordist global– local restructuring or rescaling of the national territorial state so that it be- comes a ‘glocal’ state—i.e. a polymor- phic, hollowed-out, denationalised, multitiered or multiscalar form of state territorial organisation that is the na- tional equivalent to the urban ‘exopolis’ as an expression of post-Fordist capital accumulation. (2) The ‘glocally oriented’ rescaling strate- gies of national states to enhance the locational advantages and productive ca- pacities of cities and regions in their territorial jurisdictions as maximally competitive nodes in the global economy and/or to enforce the devalorisation and revalorisation of capital within declining cities and regions. (3) Changes in cities themselves as they be- come massive, polycentric urban re- gions, megalopolises or exopolises that are turned ‘outside in’ and ‘inside out’ due to new global–local scale ge- ometries, which entail an increasingly dense ‘superimposition and interpenetra- tion’ of multiple, overlapping sub-state and suprastate scales. (4) The internationalisation of policy regimes through the roles of suprana- tional agencies such as the EU, the IMF and the World Bank in regulating and restructuring the internal territorial spaces of national states (Brenner, 1997a, 1997b, 1998, 1999a, 1999b).
  • 9. AN ENTREPRENEURIAL CITY IN ACTION 2295 In using this term, Brenner sometimes focuses on the ‘global–local’ couplet and sometimes stresses the multiplicity of the scales of terri- torial organisation that are involved in glocal- isation. Nowhere does he refer to functional scales or to the impact of cyberspace. In some contexts, he also explains the emergence of global–local state rescaling as a major stra- tegic response to the political and administrat- ive crises as well as to the economic crisis of after-Fordism. And, in the latter regard, he notes the speciŽ cally capitalist dialectic that  uctuates around the contradiction between capital’s constant striving to enhance its spa- tial mobility by diminishing its place- dependency and states’ attempts to Ž x capital within their territories through the provision of immobile, place-speciŽ c externalities than either cannot be found elsewhere or cannot be abandoned without considerable devalorisa- tion costs to capital. To avoid these problems, we propose the term ‘glurbanisation’ strategies to refer to entrepreneurial strategies that are concerned to secure the most advantageous insertion of a given city into the changing interscalar division of labour in the world economy. For, whilst glocalisation is a strategy pursued by global Ž rms that seek to exploit local differ- ences to enhance their global operations, glur- banisation is pursued by cities to enhance their place-based dynamic competitive advan- tages to capture certain types of mobile capi- tal and/or to Ž x local capital in place. More recently, of course, glocalisation has been used to refer to a wide range of strategies associated with an equally diverse range of actors that involve multiscalar strategies, jumping scales between local and global or, as noted above, transversal strategies. The key analytical (and empirical) differ- ences between glurbanisation and glocalisa- tion as we propose them within the broader framework of concerns with global–local (or, better, multiscalar) articulation are sum- marised in Table 1. This table is not intended to present a complete typology of multiscalar strategies, but aims simply to highlight some differences important for the ensuing dis- cussion. In addition to noting the four analytical and empirical distinctions between these two strategies, we would recommend that glur- banisation be analysed differently from the manner in which glocalisation is usually stud- ied.7 First, studies of glocalisation tend to work with a crude global–local dichotomy (even though actual Ž rm-, alliance- or net- work-level glocalisation strategies are often more sophisticated). This belies the multi- scalar, multitemporal nature of globalisation. Studies of glurbanisation should be attentive from the outset to the multiplicity of scales, including the creation of new scales of ac- tivity that might weaken traditional ideas of ‘nested’ territoriality. Secondly, accounts of glocalisation tend to privilege the spatial and neglect the temporal dimension of Ž rm strate- gies. In contrast, glurbanisation is explicitly concerned with how time as well as space is governed in the production of urban-based competitive advantage. This is the aspect listed in Table 1 as chronotopic governance and one that we recommend be introduced into glocalisation as well as glurbanisation studies. Thirdly, whereas past studies of glo- calisation tend to focus on the Ž rm- or sector- speciŽ c competitive advantages that it generates, future research on glurbanisation should also include its impact on the extra- economic dimensions of competitiveness. In other words, it should address the issue of structural or systemic competitiveness; and this implies that the analysis of competition would go beyond narrow economic issues to include a wide range of ‘combinations’ (Schumpeter) that bridge the economic and extra-economic. Fourthly, whereas analyses of ‘glocalisation’ tend to emphasise its advan- tages to Ž rms, our analysis is just as con- cerned with the problems posed by entrepreneurial activity. These include the tendential exhaustion of the ‘rents’ derived from any given entrepreneurial innovation (a tendency already noted by Schumpeter), the costs of ‘glurbanisation’ strategies for less privileged or powerful groups and the typical forms of failure of entrepreneurial city strate- gies. The concept of glurbanisation is very use-
  • 10. 2296 BOB JESSOP AND NGAI-LING SUM Table 1. Glurbanisation versus glocalisation Glurbanisation Glocalisation Strategic actors Cities (perhaps as national champions) Firms (perhaps in strategic alliances) Strategies Place- and space-based strategies Firm- or sector-based strategies New scales of activities Create local differences to capture Develop new forms of scalar and/or and temporalities  ows and embed mobile capital spatial division of labour Chronotopic governance Re-articulate time and space for structural Re-articulate global and local for dynamic or systemic competitive advantages competitive advantages
  • 11. AN ENTREPRENEURIAL CITY IN ACTION 2297 ful for exploring the emerging strategies of contemporary entrepreneurial cities. For it complements the concept of glocalisation and thereby provides a means of exploring the articulation between Ž rm-level, city-level and state-level strategies in the current period of globalisation. It also highlights the con- trasting moments of ‘glocalisation’ in its broadest sense—i.e. the tendential deterrito- rialising mobility of  ows in space versus reterritorialising attempts to Ž x capital in place. It is also highly relevant to the pursuit of dynamic competitive advantage in so far as ‘entrepreneurial cities’ must position themselves not only in the economic sphere, but also in the many extra-economic spheres that are so important nowadays to effective structural or systemic competition. In doing so, they continue to reproduce local differ- ences that enable transnational Ž rms to pur- sue their own ‘glocalisation’ strategies. 3. An Entrepreneurial City in Action: The Case of Hong Kong Hong Kong has a long history of urban en- trepreneurialism, with different strategies be- ing pursued as its economic and political environments changed. Our paper focuses on the period since 1979—i.e. from the year that China Ž rst opened its doors to foreign invest- ment through to Hong Kong’s current efforts to reposition itself in the light of the Asian crisis. At stake here is a complex and still evolving dialectic between glocalisation and glurbanisation strategies in the broad sense in which these terms have just been deŽ ned. The opening of China provided opportunities for Hong Kong Ž rms to adopt glocalisation strategies to enhance their competitive ad- vantage in the export market. This was partly facilitated by the corresponding glurbanisa- tion strategies of different provinces, cities and townships in southern China. This resulted in the so-called hollowing-out of Hong Kong as a manufacturing centre. The gap has been Ž lled by Hong Kong’s emerg- ence as a services centre for local, regional and international companies. In response to these changes, governmental and quasi- governmental as well as private economic actors proposed their own (competing) glur- banisation strategies for Hong Kong—some more favourable to a reinvigorated manufac- turing strategy, some more favourable to the development of a producer service role within a changing regional–global economy. These ‘glurbanisation’ responses in Hong Kong took a new turn with the outbreak of the Asian crisis and its impact on interurban, interregional and international competition in east Asia and more widely. We develop these ideas in the remainder of this paper. 3.1 ‘Glocalisation’ Strategies: From Industry to Services China’s declaration of its open door policy was followed Ž ve years later by the signing of the Sino–British Joint Declaration in 1984. This promised that Hong Kong’s capitalist way of life would not be changed for 50 years after its return to the mainland in 1997. This provided a temporary calming effect on Hong Kong society and thereby encouraged manufacturers to look for short- to medium- term opportunities in the immediate region. In particular, taking advantage of the low land and labour costs, manufacturing Ž rms relocated their activities to southern China. By the mid 1990s, almost 25 000 Hong Kong factories, mostly in textiles and clothing, toys and consumer electronics, moved there to exploit low labour and rent costs. They then employed directly about 3 million workers— i.e. three times the total manufacturing labour force left in Hong Kong. The shifting of manufacturing northwards was the result of the coalescence of glocali- sation/glurbanisation strategies pursued by various actors—private and public, economic and political—in Hong Kong and the region. More speciŽ cally, the Hong Kong govern- ment, with its commercial and industrial bases of support, continued with the so- called positive non-intervention strategy to enhance Hong Kong’s core commercial com- petitive advantages. This is re ected in in- creased emphasis on the provision of the physical, organisational and informational
  • 12. BOB JESSOP AND NGAI-LING SUM 2298 infrastructure for a developing gateway role; a continuing commitment to low and simple taxation; regulation of Ž nance and com- merce; and the maintenance of Hong Kong’s free port and free trade status. There is also an interesting complementarity here between the Hong Kong government’s strategy and the PRC’s desire to attract FDI and exper- iment with its growth-inducing potential. The resulting decentralisation strategy allowed Guangdong and Fujian to adopt preferential treatments for Hong Kong and Taiwanese investment in their development of a ‘glur- banisation’ strategy (Nee, 1992; Sum, 1996, pp. 60–62). In response to these changes, Taiwan in- dustrial and commercial capital also became more interested in establishing commercial links with the mainland through Hong Kong. Moreover, following the depreciation of Tai- wanese currency from 1986 onwards, the rising cost of land and the high standards set by the Taiwanese government’s 1984 Basic Labour Law, Ž rms also became more inter- ested in China as an industrial base. This reorientation has since been promoted by the KMT government itself on condition that trade and the movement of factors of pro- duction pass through a third site—which, in practice, usually meant Hong Kong (with Macau playing a secondary role). As a result, Hong Kong and Taiwan are the two biggest investors in Guangdong and Fujian provinces with Hong Kong alone supplying 80 per cent of all FDI. The region became a major pro- duction base for its more labour-intensive products aimed at the global market. This regional production space is also co- ordinated by private actors who are pursuing various glocalisation strategies to rearticulate time and space across borders. This is re ected in the increasing importance at- tached in Hong Kong at all levels of action to the time–space dimensions of competition. Thus, industrial and commercial capitals from Hong Kong (and Taiwan) draw on their linguistic afŽ nities and kinship ties to build socioeconomic connections in the region. They also enter strategic networks with vari- ous local Chinese public, quasi-public and private agencies in the region and consoli- date them through the socio-cultural prac- tices of guanxi (relationship). These cultural time–space aspects of ‘Greater China’ help to consolidate a coalition of local party/ administrative ofŽ cials, their afŽ liates and Hong Kong (and Taiwanese) capital. They form the social bases of support for a trans- border division of labour as Hong Kong shifts labour-intensive manufacturing to southern China. This process not only deepens Hong Kong’s entrepôt role, but also enhances its capacity as a global-regional gateway city to co-ordinate investment, trade and services in and beyond the ‘Greater China’ region. Basing themselves in Hong Kong as a gate- way city, the glocalisation strategies of capi- tal involve a rearticulation of the chronotopic dimensions of production, trade and Ž nance. More speciŽ cally, Hong Kong’s industrial, commercial and Ž nancial capital innovate new organisational practices that can be use- fully described as ‘sub-contracting manage- ment’ which involves sourcing, production, authority and distribution management. In response to the demand for global out- sourcing, industrial and commercial capital locate Chinese partners through formal con- tact and informal kinship and communal ties. This intensiŽ cation of the social space through guanxi helps to speed up the border- crossing time across the private–public div- ide as well as the rural–urban; and also to build the mutual relations needed to establish sub-contracting partnerships and joint ven- tures. After establishing these sourcing net- works, Hong Kong capital then engages in production management across time and space. The production process involves the co-ordination and supervision of time-bound projects dispersed across various sites with the more skill-intensive sub-processes in Hong Kong and the more labour-intensive ones in southern China. Production man- agers, quality controllers, line managers and so forth from Hong Kong are at the forefront here in rearticulating spatial scales and tem- poral horizons to realise time-constrained projects. This often involves further in-
  • 13. AN ENTREPRENEURIAL CITY IN ACTION 2299 tensiŽ cation of production practices, such as Ž ner differentiation of pre-production plan- ning and greater intensiŽ cation of production schedules and monitoring. Such practices build the capacity to co-ordinate transborder production processes so that goods reach the global market just-in-time. Also essential to this chronotopic gover- nance network is the building of good rela- tions with local/central ofŽ cials and cadre entrepreneurs in China. After all, these au- thorities still control enormous resources, such as land, labour, capital and regulations. In addition to production and authority man- agement, Ž nished goods in the ‘supply pipeline’ need to be exported/distributed to the global market. Distribution management, then, involves the rearticulation of factory time and global lead-time through the activi- ties of service-based Ž rms in the region as well as trading and customs authorities. This transborder private–public network is co- ordinated in the ‘electronic’ and ‘social’ spaces that synchronise transport schedules, export procedures of import/export licensing, custom liaison, international payments, in- surance, packaging and logistic management, etc., so that goods can be delivered just-in- time and ‘right-in-place’ for the global- regional buyers. Practices such as these help to speed up the transit- and pipeline-time crucial to time-bound projects (Sum, 1999, pp. 139–142). The sub-contracting management practices that are developed and co-ordinated across the border by these various political and economic actors are a form of process inno- vation. The role of these actors and practices in consolidating a cross-border ‘structured coherence’ between mode of growth and modes of regulation-governance lie at the heart of urban entrepreneurialism in Hong Kong. In this regard, Hong Kong’s competi- tive advantages (for example, quick response and lead-times for product procurement and sub-contracting, great  exibility in order- taking and product manufacturing, the ease of international sourcing, the proximity and ease of access to the PRC, the availability of trade Ž nance) are embedded in these net- works and their co-ordination of the indus- trial, commercial, Ž nancial and cultural forms of chronotopic governance. These ad- vantages were created primarily by local Ž rms and networks. This ensures the most favourable insertion of Hong Kong as a city into the emerging local–regional–global div- ision of labour and makes it attractive enough to capture and Ž x the global–regional ‘space of  ows’ in Hong Kong. In this re- gard, Hong Kong’s emerging position as a global-gateway city enables it to stay at the leading edge of the ‘fast world’ (Knox and Taylor, 1995) in an era of increasing ‘time- based’ competition. 3.2 The ‘Hollowing Out’/‘Filling In’ of Hong Kong This combination of ‘glocalisation strategies’ pursued by Hong Kong Ž rms and a ‘glurban- isation’ strategy pursued by provincial, urban and township authorities in southern China contributed to Hong Kong’s transformation from an industrial centre to a global-gateway city. But it also prompted the so-called hol- lowing-out process in its status as a manufac- turing centre. The resulting gap has been Ž lled by the growing importance of producer services such as retail and import/export trades, Ž nancial services, insurance, real es- tate and business services as well as owner- ship of premises (see Table 2). Hong Kong’s development as a service-based economy can be analysed on the material and discursive levels. The emergence of Žnance and real estate sectors. On the material level, the northward march of Hong Kong’s manufacturing turned it into a (sub-contracting) management hub. This new ‘temporal–spatial Ž x’ for the indus- trial and trade circuits has been coupled with developments on the Ž nancial front, for, since the early 1980s, Hong Kong has be- come a regional Ž nancial centre. Among contributory factors here are: Hong Kong’s market-friendly environment; the opening of China for inward and outward investment;
  • 14. BOB JESSOP AND NGAI-LING SUM 2300 Table 2. SelectedGDPatcurrent pricesby economic activity(unit percentage) 1985 1990 1995 1997 Industry 29.8 25.3 16.6 14.7 Manufacturing 21.9 17.6 8.3 6.5 Construction 5.0 5.4 5.4 5.8 Others 2.9 2.3 2.9 2.4 Services 74.5 80.3 83.8 85.2 Wholesale/retail, import/export 21.8 24.3 26.6 26.1 trades, restaurants and hotels Transport, storage and 8.1 9.4 10.1 9.3 communication Financing, insurance, real estate 16.3 20.8 24.4 26.5 and business services Community, social and 17.3 15.0 17.3 17.4 personal services Ownership of premises 11.0 10.8 13.3 13.0 Sources: Hong Kong Annual Report, Hong Kong SAR Government (various years). the growing economic importance of the Asia-PaciŽ c region; global Ž nancial liberali- sation and development of international banking and Ž nancial markets; and, develop- ments in information technology and telecommunications. Local, regional and multinational banks/Ž nancial institutions came to specialise in on-shore and off-shore activities—for example, syndicated loans for the south-east Asian region and acting as a Ž nancial entrepôt for ‘Greater China’. As a regional Ž nancial centre, Hong Kong became a net recipient of overseas funds, which amounted to about HK$138 billion in 1988. About half of these funds came from Chinese banks (Taylor, 1991, p. 48). In addition, Ž nancial deregulation in Japan and tougher competition among Japanese banks meant that Hong Kong became one of their destina- tions for off-shore activities. Thus, by the end of 1989, Japanese institutions came to dominate Hong Kong’s foreign-currency loan market and accounted for 66 per cent of Hong Kong’s total foreign currency assets (Goldstein, 1990, p. 71). This ample supply of funds was not easily absorbed by Hong Kong’s immature debt market. Thus excess capital was hunting for a new Ž eld of capital accumulation. From 1984 to 1997, it was property that provided this Ž eld. This was facilitated by the follow- ing structural and conjunctural contexts: (1) the Hong Kong government’s historical dependency upon land and property- related activities for 40 per cent of its revenue; (2) the pegged exchange rate between the Hong Kong and the US dollars, which meant that local interest rates were lower than the rate of in ation; (3) the low real interest rates, which made property purchases attractive; (4) the signing of the Sino–British Joint Declaration in 1984, which allowed the extension of land leases up to 2047; (5) the accumulated hard currency from mainland China searching for investment outlets in Hong Kong; (6) the growth in population during 1991– 93, due to an increase in the numbers of returning emigrants, imported workers and expatriates working in Hong Kong; (7) the growth in GDP per capita income at 4.4 per cent per year between 1985 and 1997; and (8) the desire of the new middle classes for property, which was seen both as a sym-
  • 15. AN ENTREPRENEURIAL CITY IN ACTION 2301 bol of better lifestyle and as a rational hedge against 8 per cent annual in ation. Together, these factors made property invest- ment and speculation a way of life and not just a form of business. Between 1985 and 1997, property estate investment and specu- lation pushed real estate prices up eight-fold. The emergence of property as an object of capital accumulation has consolidated a close relationship between Ž nance and property capital. This can be seen in three key phe- nomena: loan exposure of Ž nancial institu- tions to construction and real estate in Hong Kong averaged 40 per cent during 1983–97; more than half of the Hang Seng Index is made up of property and property-related shares; and, well-developed interlocking di- rectorships exist between banks and real es- tate/infrastructural development companies (for example, Li Ka-Shing was a deputy chairman of Hongkong Bank as well as the Chairman of Cheung Kong). This property– Ž nance relationship formed only part of a broader cross-border urban bloc that com- prised not only multinational/local banks (in the form of project Ž nance/mortgages) and construction companies (in the form of land/ property assets) but also legal/property pro- fessionals (in the form of services), the government (in the form of land and rev- enues), the middle classes (in the form of newly acquired wealth and investment) and cross-border capital from China (in the form of legal and clandestine capital). Competing discourses on Hong Kong’s glur- banisation strategies: service versus indus- try/Harvard versus MIT. This ‘Ž lling in’ of Hong Kong has given rise to continuing re exive discussions about Hong Kong’s economic future. First, worries about the de- cline of industry and the lack of high-tech investment were voiced by industrial frac- tions, especially the larger manufacturers (for example, the Federation of Hong Kong In- dustries). Secondly, rising residential and ofŽ ce rental costs were rendering the service sector vulnerable and this fraction was won- dering how best to enhance its service-based competitive advantages (for example, the Hong Kong Chamber of Commerce and the Hong Kong Coalition of Service Industries). Such issues frequently triggered public de- bates in the Legislative Councils, pro- fessional meetings and the mass media. Around 1996, these concerns were re ected in the concurrent commissioning of two con- sultancy reports that were sponsored and/or supported by different fractions of capital, public organisations (for example, the Trade Development Council and the Hong Kong Productivity Centre) and government depart- ments (for example, the Trade and Industry Departments). The two reports were pub- lished in 1997 and represented alternative glurbanisation strategies, each of which sought to envision and promote new scalar and temporal horizons for a capitalist restruc- turing of the city. They thereby re ect public debates on what constitutes the most advan- tageous mode of inserting Hong Kong into the changing multiscalar and multitemporal division of labour. In turn, this involves redeŽ ning the objects of Hong Kong’s en- trepreneurialism, its forms of competitive- ness and the ‘new combinations’ involved in creating and sustaining its structural and sys- temic competitiveness. Constructions of this kind are always contested and different frac- tions of capital and their associated interests/ networks are deeply involved in redeŽ ning the changing geography of Hong Kong’s competitiveness. In so far as a wide range of economic, political and social forces come to share one of these competing visions and mobilise behind it, Hong Kong can be seen as a re exive city committed to changing its insertion into the changing global (dis)order. The following accounts of two recent consul- tancy reports on Hong Kong aim to demon- strate the contested nature of ‘glurbanisation’ strategies of Hong Kong as an ‘entrepreneu- rial city’. The Ž rst study is a Harvard Business School consultancy report entitled The Hong Kong Advantage (Enright et al., 1997). This report was sponsored by the Vision 2047 Foundation, which groups together commer- cial and Ž nancial capital interests. This group
  • 16. BOB JESSOP AND NGAI-LING SUM 2302 promotes a revisioning of Hong Kong’s fu- ture time and space favouring its own inter- ests. The report notes Hong Kong’s manufacturing decline and the challenge of interurban competition from Shanghai, Sin- gapore, Taipei and Sydney. It promotes a vision of the city’s new identity as a ‘busi- ness/service/Ž nancial centre’ with ‘hub’ functions (see Table 3). In Schumpeterian terms, it portrays Hong Kong as a new type of urban economic space that will manage ever-expanding global–regional–local  ows of production and exchange. In this regard, its entrepreneurial ambition is to establish a ‘beyond-the-gateway’ image, or, more speciŽ cally, to offer a ‘new combination’ of ‘hub’ functions around a ‘knowledge-infor- mation-based’ economy with access to main- land China, Asia and the Asian-PaciŽ c region (Enright et al., 1997, pp. 25 and 167– 187). This urban entrepreneurialism remaps not only Hong Kong’s spatial horizons, but also its temporal horizons of action. Thus, as a key global-regional ‘hub’, it will capture and manage ‘ ows’ rather than continue to serve as an export platform. The aim is to rearticu- late relations among global, regional and local traders/investors by organising interna- tionally located systems of production, com- bining inputs from a diversity of sources in many different countries, managing a diver- sity of supply outlets, furnishing the required capital, technical support (design, construc- tion, engineering, legal, Ž nancial) and in- frastructural provisions (particularly real and virtual port and transport facilities in south- ern China and Asia). This central logistic role would enable Hong Kong to co-ordinate new temporal horizons that would relink: factory and pipeline time crucial to time- bound and compressed-time projects; and, electronic time to tame the  ow of Ž nancial, logistic information and service-based knowledge across borders as well as across the private–public divide. These new spatio-temporal horizons of ac- tion should, the report continues, be facili- tated and mediated by new urban-based institutional arrangements and practices. Thus it refers to certain features of Hong Kong’s entrepreneurial and/or governance capacities that are socially embedded on the interpersonal, institutional and societal lev- els. On an interpersonal level, the “hustle and commitment strategies” [sic] of Hong Kong’s “merchant manufacturers” should be combined with the embedded institutions of “government as referee” and with the activi- ties of “entrepreneurial and managerial Ž rms” from Hong Kong and abroad (Enright et al., 1997, pp. 45– 46, 127, and 34– 40). These networks would be supported by an existing societal ethos of “hard-working peo- ple” but this entrepreneurial culture must nonetheless be helped to win greater compet- itiveness. This is to be achieved through the provision of “inputs to industry” (p. 85) and by promoting strategic clusters of industries such as property, construction, infrastructure, business and Ž nancial services, transport and logistics, light manufacturing and trading, and tourism. Such clusters and their linkages enable them to “draw upon common skill bases or inputs, and reinforce each other’s competitive positions through dynamic inter- action” (Enright et al., 1997, p. 95). In short, this Porterian construction of Hong Kong’s structural competitiveness promotes a space- based and interscalar ‘glurbanisation’ strat- egy to reinsert Hong Kong favourably into changing  ows produced by regional and global restructuring. The MIT report, entitled Made by Hong Kong (Berger and Lester, 1997), offers a more place-based account of Hong Kong’s entrepreneurial future (see Table 3). This report is sponsored by industrial capital with the support of certain parts of the bureauc- racy (most notably the Hong Kong Govern- ment Industry Department and the Hong Kong Productivity Council). It portrays Hong Kong as locked into a ‘made by Hong Kong’ manufacturing trajectory—i.e. as or- ganising the low-cost manufacture of ‘Hong Kong’ goods in offshore locations such as southern China and other parts of Asia. The report argues that this trajectory will prove “unsustainable” due to rising labour and land costs in Guangdong province, to the “craze
  • 17. 2303 AN ENTREPRENEURIAL CITY IN ACTION Table 3. Two competing glurbanisation strategies for Hong Kong as an ‘entrepreneurial city’ in 1997 The Hong Kong Advantage Made by Hong Kong Object(s) of Decline of manufacturing From ‘Made by Hong Kong’ entrepreneurial Promote trade, Ž nance and to ‘Made in Hong Kong’ intervention high-tech industry City identity Business/service/Ž nance centre Hi-tech manufacturing centre Information hub · Brand-name production Logistic hub · Original design manufacturing Innovative practices Purpose Manage the  ows Fix capital/technology in place New scales of activities Global – regional – local Regional – local technology (re)articulation diffusion (with hints of global) New temporal horizons Rearticulating transit/pipeline time Research and training time Importance of electronic time for higher-value products Development of electronic time New governance capacities Dynamic clusters and linkages R&D base Property, construction Input to all industries Input to technology · Location (proximity to China) · Government fundings · Infrastructure (airport, port, telecom) · Private R&D investment · Capital and Ž nance · Incentives for research · Capital goods and components · Information services and technologies · Human resources · Regional and international specialists Form of competitiveness Space-based and interscalar competitiveness Place-based form of competitiveness Fraction(s) of capital Commercial and Ž nancial capital Industrial capital (and its associated networks) (and its associated networks)
  • 18. BOB JESSOP AND NGAI-LING SUM 2304 for property” in the region and to the com- petitive challenge coming from Japan’s suc- cessful organisation of its own regional networks in the area (Berger and Lester, 1997, pp. 52–57). The best response to such uncertainties for Hong Kong is said to be ‘climb the technology ladder’ by producing higher- value-added goods in Hong Kong itself. The report deploys the symbols of ‘Made in Hong Kong’ and Hong Kong as a ‘high-tech manu- facturing centre’ to reorient its future com- petitiveness and urban character. Seen in Schumpeterian terms, this reconstruction seeks to narrate Hong Kong in terms of a new type of urban economic space that seeks to ‘reŽ x’ its role as a base for production. The invocation of ‘technology’ is the key symbol here in building ‘Hong Kong’s new engine for growth’. And this will in- volve a different chronotopic Ž x from that involved in the previous ‘made by Hong Kong’ mode of growth. It involves new methods of producing and organising socio- economic space and will require the support of government. Spatially, the team envisions a global– regional–local diffusion of technology that could launch Hong Kong on the path to its own brand-name production and original de- sign manufacturing. This place-based com- petitiveness involves intensifying (including compressing) research and training time as well as exploiting possibilities in electronic time. This remixing of time–space horizons requires  ows of information conducive to the development of an R&D base crucial to Hong Kong’s competitiveness. This in turn requires new urban-based institutional ar- rangements and practices. Accordingly, the report concentrates on institutional changes required to boost the entrepreneurial and self-governance capacities of Hong Kong’s technological base. These include: (1) acquiring technical knowledge from the PRC, diasporic Chinese, international experts and multinational corporations; (2) promoting R&D agglomeration econom- ies based on universities, technology- based enterprises, education institutes, (virtual) science parks and private Ž rms; (3) acquiring new inputs such as govern- ment fundings, human resources and in- formation technology; and (4) strengthening the technological capabili- ties of government by injecting more technical expertise and raising the proŽ le of technology-related policies; etc. In short, we can argue that this construction of Hong Kong’s structural competitiveness is based on a place-based notion. 4. The Asian Crisis and Hong Kong’s New Urban Identities These competing ‘glurbanisation’ visions re- veal the contested nature of Hong Kong’s urban restructuring and its embedded social and economic relations. This debate was, however, interrupted by Hong Kong’s tran- sition from a British colony to a Special Administrative Region in 1997; and, more importantly and unexpectedly, by the Asian crisis as it unfolded in 1997–99. 4.1 The Asian Crisis On February 1997, speculators Ž rst attacked the Thai bhat and the Bank of Thailand allowed the bhat to  oat on 2 July 1997. This triggered a Ž nancial contagion that quickly spread from Thailand to Indonesia, Malaysia, South Korea, the Phillippines, and then Hong Kong (Sum, 1999). In Hong Kong, the dollar came under speculative pressure on several occasions in July, August and October 1997. These currency attacks put the government on short-term crisis management. It inter- vened in the money market initially by push- ing up interest rates in the interbanking sector and later by imposing penalty interest on borrowing of the Hong Kong dollar. The government was able to maintain the pegged exchange rate under conditions of high inter- est rates, capital  ight from the Hong Kong dollar and reduced external demand. These pushed the local stock index and residential
  • 19. AN ENTREPRENEURIAL CITY IN ACTION 2305 property prices down by over 50 per cent between October 1997 and June 1998. This asset depreciation, especially in the property sector, cut at the heart of Hong Kong’s inter- nal ‘growth’ dynamics, since this had devel- oped since the opening of China. This bursting of the ‘property bubble’ has given rise to fear among this property-related bloc about further asset depreciation. In order to prevent the asset from further depreciating, the government’s short-term strategies were: to freeze land sales (until April 1999); to allocate HK$1390 million for home-buyer loans; and, to grant tax rebates to property owners. The Hong Kong dollar came under further attack in August 1998 when the yen depreci- ated against the dollar, with hedge funds selling the Hong Kong stock market short in the expectation that the index would fall as interest rates rose. Speculative attacks pro- pelled signiŽ cant amounts of capital out ow as some people believed that this might also force a yuan devaluation. This time, the government reacted with more short-term measures which included: drawing on its re- serves to buy US$ 15 billion worth of se- lected Hong Kong shares (60 per cent of these were property related—higher than this sector’s weight in the stock market); and, introducing a package of technical measures to strengthen the transparency and operation of the linked exchange rate system (for ex- ample, a rediscount facility to reduce interest rate volatility). The pegged system was once again maintained, but at the expense of high interest rates, weak domestic demand and rising unemployment. Hong Kong’s GDP fell 5 per cent and the unemployment rate had reached 6 per cent at the beginning of 1999. However, wages and rents are still high. In April 1999, the government resumed land sales—an action that was seen as a continuing of its support for the property sector. These are short-term tactics that seek to maintain the conŽ dence of the property- related urban bloc. However, the debate over what constitutes Hong Kong’s ‘glurbanisa- tion strategy’ and new urban identity is far from being over. 4.2 A New Urban Identity for a Crisis-ridden Hong Kong The service versus industry (or Harvard ver- sus MIT) debate took a new turn when the crisis began to stabilise in early 1999. The Asian crisis has disarticulated the previous structured coherence of Hong Kong’s politi- cal economy and has exposed it to several challenges: (1) the decline in Hong Kong’s role as agent for China’s exports; (2) over-dependence on property sector; (3) the vulnerability of Ž nancial and other services; (4) the effects of recession (see, for exam- ple, negative growth rate, fall in asset values 6 per cent unemployment rate); (5) competition from other regional cities, such as Shanghai and Singapore; and (6) the rising ‘tide of the information revol- ution’. Given that Hong Kong has become a global– regional–gateway city dependent on the local real estate sector as well as cross-border manufacturing, innovative attempts to recast Hong Kong’s competitiveness cannot be en- tirely divorced from this historical growth path. Up to the time of writing, private and public actors alike are urgently seeking to construct new objects and projects of urban governance that might help to rebuild the crisis-ridden economy. One high-proŽ le ob- ject-project is the ‘Cyberport’ (see Table 4) that was originally the ‘brain child’ of ‘Hong Kong’s Bill Gates’ (Richard Li) and his Singapore-based corporation called PaciŽ c Century. Li’s (and PaciŽ c Century’s) idea was to create a comprehensive facility designed to foster the development of Hong Kong’s infor- mation services sector and to enhance Hong Kong’s position as the premier in- formation and telecommunications hub in Asia (Hong Kong Cyberport, 1999, p. 1). In addition, the Cyber-port is meant to attract, nurture
  • 20. BOB JESSOP AND NGAI-LING SUM 2306 Table 4. A new economic object of urban governance: Cyberport Cost HK$13 billion (US$1.68 billion) Size 64 acres (25.6 hectares) Location Telegragh Bay, Pokfulam Aims “To create a world class location for the conduct of a variety of activities which through the use of information technologies, can leverage Hong Kong existing strengths in the service sector (e.g., in Ž nancial, media, retail, transportation, education, and tourism services)” (Hong Kong Cyberport, 1999, p. 1). Built Environment I Cyber facilities (2/3 of the site) Fibre-optic wiring Satellite signal senders Built-in high-speed modems Cyberlibrary Media laboratories and studio facilities Built Environment II Real estate (1/3 of the site) Houses and apartments Hotels Retail Completion date 2007 (commencing from 2002) Job creation 4 000 during construction 12 000 professional jobs on completion (10 per cent from outside Hong Kong) Partners PaciŽ c Century CyberWorks (HK$7 billion equity capital) Government (land worth HK$6 billion) Cluster of tenants Multinational corporations (Microsoft, IBM, Oracle, HP, Softbank, Yahoo!, Hua Wei, Sybase) Local tenants of small to medium-sized information-technology companies Metaphors/images used ‘Silicon Valley’ and ‘catching up’ and retain the relevant innovative talent necessary to build a cyber-culture critical mass in Hong Kong (Hong Kong Cyber- port, 1999, p. 1). In this regard, Li’s (and PaciŽ c Century’s) vision is interesting in two aspects. First, it can be seen as a re exive reinvention of the Harvard report. It adopts the idea of a ser- vice-based cluster; but one that narrates it in terms of the metaphor ‘Silicon Valley’ and suggests that the Cyberport could help Hong Kong to ‘catch up’ with the ‘information revolution’. In other words, the creation of the Cyberport as an economic object can rearticulate Hong Kong’s imagined time and space not only to global-regional ‘trade and Ž nancial  ows’ but also to global ‘infor- mation  ows’. More speciŽ cally, this project aims to redeŽ ne Hong Kong’s competitive advan- tages and chronotopic governance by: captur- ing global ‘information  ows’ and managing them within the service-space of Hong Kong and its broader region (for example, as an e-commerce hub); connecting Hong Kong’s services to fast cybertime and the knowl- edge-based economy; and, consolidating a social space in which to build a ‘cyber cul- ture critical mass’ that links the global, re- gional and local. This time–space reimagination can be seen as an innovative
  • 21. AN ENTREPRENEURIAL CITY IN ACTION 2307 entrepreneurial city vision to create a new techno-urban identity. Secondly, given that the Cyberport is an imagined service cluster that will be built to capture the information-technology  ows, this new object can symbolically (and, per- haps, materially) bridge the traditional ser- vice–technology–property divide in the cityspace of Hong Kong. It highlights the role of (information) technology in expand- ing the activities of traditional service clus- ters—a critical mass can be (partly) nurtured by the physical form of the built environment that is modelled on the ‘Silicon Valley’. The transversal potential of this construction has not gone unnoticed by the government and its advisory agency (the Commission for Innovation and Technology). In fact, the idea was selected and (partly) appropriated by the government when the Financial Secretary unveiled it in the 1999 Budget. After the ofŽ cial announcement, this new object of urban governance seems to have resonated within a global–regional–local epistemic community comprising local capi- tal (for example, Richard Li and the PaciŽ c Century), the government (for example, the Chief Executive, the Financial Secretary, the Commission on Innovation and Technology, the Secretary for Information and Broadcast- ing), quasi-governmental organisations (for example, Hong Kong Industrial Technology Centre) and global–regional capitals (for ex- ample, Microsoft’s Bill Gates, Yahoo!’s Jerry Yeung and IBM’s Craig Barrett). The latter group of ‘cyber-gods’  ew to Hong Kong, publicly endorsed the idea and even highlighted their own roles therein. A tech- nocultural regime of truth is beginning to emerge in this network of ‘infopreneurs’, which cuts across the private–public as well as global–regional–local spheres. But this emerging regime of truth has also encountered resistance. Some market ana- lysts (for example, Webb) criticise the Cy- berport idea as comprising little more than “Cyber villas by sea” (i.e. a real estate proj- ect as opposed to a high-tech project) and claim there “is no ‘Silicon Valley’ ” (Webb, 1999). Being left out of an important stra- tegic project, 10 real estate developers jointly denounced the government’s decision-mak- ing process as being ‘not open for bidding’ and declared that the government is using residential land to subsidise the Cyberport project. The Democratic Party, for different reasons, challenged the government for lack of transparency, creating ‘favouritism/ cronyism’ and departing from its ‘laissez- faire’ policy. Despite these challenges, the emerging techno-urban discourse/identity continues to resonate and has gathered some strength in reorganising and reregularising economic practices. Notable examples include new consortia of property developers proposing new innovative projects. Large developers such as Sun Hung Kai Properties (SHKP) and Hutchison Whampoa have reinvented themselves as Internet companies. SHKP created its own Internet arm (SunEvision) and, together with the Hong Kong Industrial Technology Centre (HKITC), launched the Cyberincubator project in August 1999. Un- der this latter scheme, developers would pro- vide rent-free space for new ‘infopreneurs’ for 3 years in return for 10 per cent stakes in their businesses. Other developers such as Cheung Kong (Holdings), Henderson Land Development, New World Development and Sino Land are planning to participate in simi- lar rent-for-equity programmes. The Chief Executive, Tung Chee-Hwa, visited Silicon Valley in July 1999 to build new linkages with the local Internet communities. The Hong Kong-Silicon Valley Association, which is mediated by a Chinese diaspora network, was set up to enhance possible glo- bal–local  ows of knowledge, expertise and manpower. Some investors even switched from blue chips to Internet and technology and Internet-related stocks—the share price of PaciŽ c Century CyberWorks rose 1280 per cent when it Ž rst came onto the market in May 1999.8 In this regard, it can be argued that the technocultural imagination has cre- ated a post-crisis euphoria that may be con- ducive towards the rebuilding of a new form of urban governance that cuts across the global–regional–local scales as well as across
  • 22. BOB JESSOP AND NGAI-LING SUM 2308 different fractions of commercial, Ž nancial, property and technological capital. In ad- dition to its potential to re-ally different cap- itals (and their organisational and interorganisational setups) for new strategic projects, it is also facilitating the rebuilding of cross-border private–public alliance based on the politics of (Internet) optimism. Riding on this politics of (Internet) opti- mism, the Cyberport imagination was further reinforced and broadened in the Second and Final Report of the Commission of Inno- vation and Technology published in June 1999. Acknowledging the importance of In- ternet-based services linked to the Cyberport project, the Commission reintroduces some place-based manufacturing recommenda- tions—some of which resonate with the MIT report (for example, institutional/organisa- tional changes such as institutional arrange- ments, building up human capital, fostering innovation and technology culture, and cre- ating an enabling business environment). However, it is also re exively seeking new niches that would go beyond the MIT sug- gestions. More speciŽ cally, one such niche recommended by the Commission is the building of a ‘Silicon Harbour’. This was planned to comprise a semi-conductor manu- facturing project that would allegedly be able to ‘leapfrog’ existing microchip fabrication facilities. This state-of-the-art factory would cost US$1.2 billion and comprise 4 factories built in phases, along with infrastructure and supporting facilities, on over 200 hectares and would eventually accommodate 200–300 companies. Its main aim was to by-pass the PC age and enter directly into the ASICs (application-speciŽ c integrated circuits) era by 2003.9 This reintroduction of high-tech manufacturing strategy back to Hong Kong is not without sceptics, who see the chip- manufacturing venture as going in the op- posite direction from a service-based e-commerce and information highway. In- deed, at the time of writing, it seems unlikely that the Silicon Harbour project will be realised. More recently (February 2000), the Com- mission on Strategic Development, with the approval of the Chief Executive, has rein- forced the importance of the Ž nancial and business services sector. This is illustrated by an ofŽ cial blueprint for transforming Hong Kong into Asia’s ‘world city’ that would rival the positions of London and New York in Europe and North America respectively. This would involve strengthening Hong Kong’s links with the Pearl River delta and other mainland regions (such as the Yangtze delta and basin and key central and western regions) as well as enhancing its ability to exploit China’s imminent entry into the World Trade Organisation and position itself as a ‘knowledge-based economy’. This blue- print envisages a complex array of private– public partnerships and networks co-operating under Hong Kong’s leadership to promote the overall competitiveness of an emerging multicentred city-region, not only in economic terms but also in cultural and community matters. This long-term develop- ment plan is explicitly phrased in en- trepreneurial terms, emphasises the importance of marketing Hong Kong as a world-class city and is strongly committed to promoting a wide range of innovative, high- tech Ž nancial and business services to secure its position within an evolving interscalar division of labour (Commission on Strategic Development, 2000). 5. Hong Kong and its New Interurban Competition: The Siliconisation of Asia Hong Kong is not the only city that has imagined an information-technology fu- ture—whether service- or manufacturing- based. Inspired and worried by the hi-tech boom in the US, other major cities in east Asia are caught in this technology race. Gov- ernments and different fractions/scales of capital—for example, venture capital funds, investment banks, real-estate companies, In- ternet (mega-)corporations—in different ur- ban centres co-ordinate and market themselves by offering different ‘temporal– spatial’ Ž xes that are related to some form of hi-tech settlement such as Singapore’s ‘Intel-
  • 23. AN ENTREPRENEURIAL CITY IN ACTION 2309 Table 5. Hi-tech clusters in Singapore and Malaysia Singapore’s Malaysia’s Science Hub Multi-media Supercorridor Project cost US$20 billion US$2.9 billion Size 434 acres 750 sq kma Major tenants Dell Microsoft National University of Singapore Intel Singapore Polytechnic Nippon Telegraph and Telephone Completion date Before 2013 (Ž rst phase in 2002) 2020 Niches R&D development Software Multimedia products a The Supercorridor connects Kuala Lumpur and its airport. ligent Island’ and ‘Science Hub’, Malaysia’s ‘Multimedia Supercorridor’ (see Table 5). Singapore, a long-standing threat to Hong Kong’s aim of becoming the dominant re- gional Ž nancial centre, is entering a new round of competition in the information age. As early as 1986, Singapore formulated its Ž rst national IT plan to enhance competitive- ness. In 1991, the National Computer Board initiated the IT2000 vision. This examined how IT might be leveraged to improve busi- ness performance and the quality of life. In 1996, the Singapore ONE (One Network for Everybody) was announced with the aim of establishing Singapore as the world’s ‘intelli- gent island’ modelled upon the ‘Silicon Val- ley’. This project involves building the world’s Ž rst nation-wide broadband network that wires up the entire island. This national network aims to deliver a new level of inter- active, multimedia applications and services to its new breed of ‘netizens’. Up to 1999, the total number of users was about 70 000. More recently, Singapore has proposed a ‘Science Hub’ that aims to attract hi-tech companies to engage in R&D development (see Table 5). In 1996, Malaysia’s Prime Minister, Ma- hathir Mohamad, launched the idea of a ‘Multimedia Supercorridor’ (MSC) as the country’s new ‘thrust area for sustainable growth’ (see Table 5). It covers 750 sq km stretching south from the federal capital to the new Kuala Lumpur International Airport and also encompasses Putrajaya, the govern- ment’s new administrative centre. Its aim is to become a test-bed for IT and multimedia solutions. In July 1999, the Ž rst township, Cyberjaya, was launched claiming to be a ‘Far East version of Silicon Valley’ which is ‘intelligent, hi-tech, low-density and environ- mentally friendly’. It would also be the MSC’s ‘nerve centre’ housing hi-tech com- panies, research centres and a multimedia university (Agence France Presse, 1999). It has already attracted 21 companies to form the core and is offering tax breaks and fast communication links to attract the regional headquarters of existing multinational com- panies as well as new communication and multimedia Ž rms. Scattered around Asia, there are other planned information technology clusters— for example, Beijing’s Zhongguancun area. They are at some stage of high-proŽ le devel- opment, each one a self-proclaimed ‘next Silicon Valley’ with a ‘Silicon Valley state of mind’. This process of siliconisation in east/south-east Asia marks one of the ways these cities aim to compete. Each is launch- ing an aggressive public-relations campaign both locally and internationally to market a niche that goes beyond its (current or future diminishing capacity to provide) cheap land and labour. At the time of writing, the Singa- pore ONE is feeling the pinch from the fast- track approach of Hong Kong’s Cyberport and Malaysia’s Multimedia Supercorridor.
  • 24. BOB JESSOP AND NGAI-LING SUM 2310 Thus Singapore ONE is now seeking to re- gain the initiative by boosting its usage and consolidating additional global–local partner- ships that might wish to use Singapore as a springboard to other broadband cities in Asia (James, 1999). 6. Conclusions The analysis presented above is still prelimi- nary for two reasons. It is based on an emerging approach to entrepreneurial cities that needs further theoretical development and reŽ nement; and it is illustrated from case studies that are still at the early stages of design and implementation. Nonetheless we believe that four themes are worth restating as key elements in an emerging research agenda on interurban competition in the cur- rent period of capitalist restructuring. First, we believe that the crisis of the national framework of the ‘spatio–temporal Ž x’ and compromise that helped to sustain post-war growth during the period of At- lantic Fordism and the emergence of national security and/or developmental states in east Asia has contributed to a ‘relativisation of scale’. This phenomenon refers to the fact that no new scale has emerged to replace the primacy of the national level in the organis- ation and regularisation of the global econ- omy. This is associated with the search for new forms of chronotopic (time–space) gov- ernance as well as new forms of material and immaterial economic, political and social or- ganisation. Indeed, we Ž nd competing spatial and scalar strategies on many different lev- els, pursued by a wide range of actors; but these have not yet evolved into an overall pattern of structural coherence analogous to the post-war period with its primacy of the national. Secondly, in exploring the changing role of cities in this regard, we believe that it is useful to develop a Schumpeterian analysis of the entrepreneurial city. We believe that it is justiŽ ed to treat cities as actors under certain conditions and that these are closely bound up with capacities to realise particular discursive-material accumulation strategies and hegemonic projects. Even if this is re- jected, it is certainly the case that urban blocs claiming to speak for and on behalf of cities or regions as ‘spaces for themselves’ (Lipi- etz, 1985/1994) have become more explicitly entrepreneurial on all three criteria intro- duced above. Thirdly, in this context we believe it is worth distinguishing between ‘glocalisation’ and ‘glurbanisation’ in terms of whether it is a Ž rm-level or city-level strategy that is at stake. We concede that both terms are mis- leading in so far as they seem to operate with a simple global–local or a simple global– urban dichotomy, which thereby fails to grasp the real complexity and perplexity of the proliferation of increasingly tangled places, spaces and scales which can no longer be treated as if they were ‘nested’ like so many Russian dolls. But it is this very complexity, perplexity, proliferation and tan- gledness that poses uncertainties and risks demanding new entrepreneurial orientations. The concept of ‘glurbanisation’ represents a Ž rst attempt to address some of these prob- lems from the viewpoint of the city as actor rather than from the viewpoint of the Ž rm. As we have also noted elsewhere, however, ‘glurbanisation’ can also be seen as a state- level response in so far as cities are coming to replace Ž rms as ‘national champions’ in international competition (Jessop, 1998; Jessop and Sum, 1998). Fourthly, we also relate these changes to shifts in the modalities of competition in an increasingly ‘globally integrated’ but still multiscalar, unevenly developing and tangled economy, because these shifts have modiŽ ed the nature of interurban as well as inter- national competition. Indeed, with the in- creasing interest in dynamic competitive advantages and the bases of structural and/ or systemic competitiveness, the extra- economic dimensions of cities have gained as much signiŽ cance as what used to be seen as their economic dimensions. So-called natural economic factor endowments have become far less important (despite the con- tinuing path-dependent aspects of the posi- tioning of places in urban hierarchies); and
  • 25. AN ENTREPRENEURIAL CITY IN ACTION 2311 socially constructed, socially regularised and socially embedded factors have become more important for interurban competitiveness. This is why urban entrepreneurialism comes to be so signiŽ cant in shaping the forms of urban hierarchies (especially in their middle ranks) and the character of global city net- works. Certainly the capacity to remain at the top of the hierarchy or to move up it depends on cities’ capacities and strategies for acquir- ing complex strategic activities and/or pro- moting innovation in the areas we have sketched (see Krätke, 1995, pp. 136–142). Notes 1. On earlier power blocs and fractions of capital, see Sum (1995). 2. On the now superseded proposal for a sci- ence park, see Wong (1998). Another project is the Disneyland Themepark which is being promoted in Hong Kong in rivalry with Shanghai. 3. For a rational choice approach to en- trepreneurial cities that does make these (un- realistic) assumptions, see Peterson (1981). 4. These boundaries are not necessarily singular or coincident; they can be eccentric and in- volve linkages with an eccentric hierarchy of other scales. 5. On this initial usage, see Japan Machinery Exporters’ Association, 1989, cited in Ruigrok and van Tulder, 1996, p. 178n. 6. Glocalisation has also been used to refer to a company’s attempt to become accepted as a ‘local citizen’ in a different trade bloc, while transferring as little control as possible over its areas of strategic concern’ (Ruigrok and van Tulder, 1996, p. 179). 7. These recommendations could also be fruit- fully applied to glocalisation. 8. CyberWorks was formerly known as Tricom Holdings. It is an arm of the PaciŽ c Century and is responsible for the Cyberport project. It has since been listed on the Hong Kong Stock Exchange as PaciŽ c Century Cyber- Works. 9. ASICs are used to produce mobile phones, handheld computers, smart blender and intel- ligent microwave ovens and are expected to replace PCs as the chief growth engine. References AGENCE FRANCE PRESS (1999) Multimedia charts new growth path for Malaysia, 8 July (wysiwyg://38/http:www.globalarchive.ft.com/ search/FTJSPController.ht). BARNES, W. R. and LEDUBUR, L. C. (1991) To- ward a new political economy of metropolitan regions, Environment and Planning C, 9, pp. 127–141. BERGER, S. and LESTER, R. (1997) Made by Hong Kong. Hong Kong: Oxford University Press. BRAUDEL, F. (1984) The Perspective of the World. London: Collins. BRENNER, N. (1997a) Global cities, glocal states: global city formation and state territorial re- structuring in contemporary Europe, Review of International Political Economy, 5, pp. 1–37. BRENNER, N. (1997b) State territorial restructuring and the production of spatial scale: urban and regional planning in the Federal Republic of Germany, 1960–1990, Political Geography, 16, pp. 273–306. BRENNER, N. (1998) Re-scaling state space: urban regions, uneven development, and the contradictory political geography of neoliber- alism. Paper prepared for the RIPE conference on ‘Globalisation, State, Violence’, University of Sussex, April. BRENNER, N. (1999a) Globalisation as reterritori- alisation: the re-scaling of urban governance in the European Union, Urban Studies, 36, pp. 431–451. BRENNER, N. (1999b) Beyond state-centrism? Space, territoriality and geographical scale in globalization studies, Theory and Society, 28, pp. 39–78. CASTELLS, M (1997) The Rise of Network Society. Oxford: Blackwell. CHESNAIS, F. (1986) Science, technology and competitiveness, STI Review, 1, pp. 85–129. CLARKE, S. and GAILE, G. (1998) The Work of Cities. Minneapolis, MI: University of Minnesota Press. COMMISSION ON STRATEGIC DEVELOPMENT (2000) Bringing the Vision to Life: Hong Kong’s Long-term Development Needs and Goals. Hong Kong: Central Policy Unit, Hong Kong Special Administrative Region. COX, K. R. and MAIR, A. (1991) From localised social structures to localities as agents, Environment and Planning A, 23, pp. 197– 214. DALY, G. (1993) The discursive construction of economic space, Economy and Society, 20, pp. 79–102. ENRIGHT, M., SCOTT, E. and DODWELL, D. (1997) The Hong Kong Advantage. Hong Kong: Oxford University Press. GOLDSTEIN, C. (1990) High stakes: Japanese share of overseas investment surges, Far Eastern Economic Review, 28 June, pp. 71–72. HALL, P. (1998) Cities and Civilisation. London: Weidenfeld & Nicolson. HALL, T. and HUBBARD, P. (1996) The en-
  • 26. BOB JESSOP AND NGAI-LING SUM 2312 trepreneurial city: new urban politics, new urban geographies?, Progress in Human Geography, 20, pp. 153–174. HARDING, A. (1995) European city regimes? In- ter-urban competition in the new Europe. Paper presented to an Economic and Social Research Council Local Governance Conference, Exeter, September. HARVEY, D. (1989) From managerialism to en- trepreneurialism: the transformation of urban governance in late capitalism, GeograŽ ska Annaler, Series B: Human Geography, 71B(1), pp. 3–17. HONG KONG CYBERPORT (1999) Hong Kong Cyber-port (http://www.cyber-port.com/; read on 9 June). JACOBS, J. (1984) Cities and the Wealth of Nations. Harmondsworth: Penguin. JAMES, K. (1999) Singapore ONE Shifting to Higher Gear, Singapore Business Times, 30 August. JESSOP, B. (1997) The entrepreneurial city: re-imaging localities, redesigning economic governance, in: N. JEWSON and S. MACGREGOR (Eds) Realizing Cities: New Spatial Divisions and Social Transformation, pp. 28– 41. London: Routledge. JESSOP, B. (1998) The enterprise of narrative and the narrative of enterprise: place marketing and the entrepreneurial city, in: T. HALL and P. HUBBARD (Eds) The Entrepreneurial City, pp. 7–99. Chichester: Wiley. JESSOP, B. (1999) The changing governance of welfare: recent trends in its primary functions, scale, and modes of coordination, Social Policy and Administration, 33, pp. 348–359. JESSOP, B. and SUM, N.-L. (1998) Interscalar strategies in a ‘glurbanizing’ city: chronotopic governance and urban entrepreneurship in Hong Kong. Paper presented at the Inter- national Workshop on ‘Globalizing Asian Cities’, Helsinki, May. (Paper available from either author.) JONAS, A. E. G. and WILSON, D. (Eds) (1999) The Urban Growth Machine: Critical Perspectives Two Decades Later. New York: State Univer- sity of New York Press. KNOX, P. and TAYLOR, P. J. (Eds) (1995) World Cities in a World System. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. KRÄTKE, S. (1995) Stadt, Raum, Ökonomie: Ein- führung in aktuelle Problemfelder der Stad- tökonomie und Wirtschaftsgeographie. Basel: Birkhäuser Verlag. LE GALÈS, P. and HARDING, A. (1998) Cities and states in Europe, West European Politics, 21(3), pp. 120–145. LEICHT, K. T. and JENKINS, J. C. (1994) Three strategies of state economic development: entrepreneurial, industrial recruitment, and deregulation policies in the American states, Economic Development Quarterly, 8, pp. 256– 269. LIM, C. Y. (1990) The Schumpeterian road to af uence and communism, Malaysian Journal of Economic Studies, 27, pp. 213– 223. LIPIETZ, A. (1985/1994) The national and the regional: their autonomy vis-à-vis the capitalist world crisis, in: R. P. PALEN and B. GILLS (Eds) Transcending the State–Global Divide: A Neo- statist Agenda in International Relations, pp. 23– 43. Boulder, CO: Lynne Rienner. MESSNER, D. (1996) Die Netzwerkgesellschaft: Wirtschaftliche Entwicklung und internationale Wettbewerbsfähigkeit als Probleme gesellschaftlicher Steuerung. Köln: Weltforum Verlag. NEE, V. (1992) Organisational dynamics of mar- ket transitions: hybrid forms of property rights, and mixed economy in China, Administrative Science Quarterly, 37, pp. 1– 27. OECD (1991) Cities and New Technologies. Paris: OECD. PARKINSON, M. and HARDING, A. (1995) European cities towards 2000: entrepreneurialism, com- petition and social exclusion, in: M. RHODES (Ed.) The Regions and the New Europe: Pat- terns in Core and Periphery Development, pp. 53–77. Manchester: Manchester University Press. PETERSON, P. E. (1981) City Limits. Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press. POSTONE, M. (1993) Time, Labour and Social Domination: A Reinterpretation of Marx’s Critical Theory. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. RUIGROK, W. and TULDER, R. VAN (1996) The Logic of International Restructuring. London: Routledge. SCHUMPETER, J. A. (1934) Theory of Economic Development: An Inquiry into ProŽ ts, Capital, Credit, Interest and the Business Cycle. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press. STORPER, M. (1997) The city: the centre of economic re exivity, The Service Industries Journal, 17, pp. 1– 27. SUM, N-L. (1995) More than a ‘war of words’: identity, politics and the struggle for dominance during the recent ‘political reform’ period in Hong Kong, Economy and Society, 24, pp. 67– 100. SUM, N-L. (1996) ‘Greater China’ and global– regional–local dynamics in the post-Cold War era, in: I. COOK, M. DOEL, and R. LI (Eds) Fragmented Asia: Regional Integration and National Disintegration in PaciŽ c Asia, pp. 53– 74. Aldershot: Avebury. SUM, N-L. (1999) Rethinking globalization: re- articulating the spatial scales and temporal horizons of trans-border spaces, in: K. OLDS, P.
  • 27. AN ENTREPRENEURIAL CITY IN ACTION 2313 DICKEN, P. E. KELLY ET AL. (Eds) Globalization and the Asia-PaciŽ c, pp. 129–148. London: Routledge. SWYNGEDOUW, E. A. (1997) Neither global nor local: ‘glocalization’ and the politics of scale, in: K. COX (Ed.) Spaces of Globalization: Reasserting the Power of the Local, pp. 137– 166. New York: Guilford. TAYLOR, M. (1991) Boom with a queue, Far Eastern Economic Review, 22 August, pp. 48– 49. TAYLOR, P. J. (1995) World cities and territorial states, in: P. L. KNOX and P. J. TAYLOR (Eds) World Cities in a World-system, pp. 48–62. Cambridge, MA: Cambridge University Press. VELTZ, P. (1996) Mondialisation de Villes et Territoires. Paris: Presses Universitaires de France. WEBB, D. M. (1999) PaciŽ c Century CyberWork, 5 May (http://webb-site.com/articles/pccyber- wok.htm). WONG, P. (1998) Landscape of hegemony and ‘entrepreneureality’: the high technology industry in Hong Kong. Unpublished PhD thesis, Lancaster University.