SlideShare a Scribd company logo
1 of 53
Macroeconomics
Name:
Course:
Instructor:
Institution:
Date of Submission
The Key Issues Addressed in the Paper
How the Federal Reserve System and the Treasury Relate;
The Pre-Crisis Cash Management;
Cash Management by Treasury Following the Onset of the
Crisis; and
The Treatment of the Financial Crisis.
How the Federal Reserve System and the Treasury Relate
The U.S. Treasury channels a good part of its receipts the TGA;
It disburses the payments made into the same account;
This ensures a continuous fund flows from the depository
institutions to TGA and back again;
The interface required joint management between Treasury and
Fed during the crisis
How the Federal Reserve System and the Treasury Relate
There are a number of ways in which the roles of the Treasury
and the Fed relate even though they may seem sufficiently
distinct. The U.S. Treasury channels a good part of its receipts
the TGA (Adrian, 2009). Similarly, it disburses the payments
made into the same account. This ensures that there is always
continuity in fund flows from the depository institutions to this
account and back again. This continuous flow of funds between
the account and the deposit-taking financial institutions played
a crucial during the Financial Crisis of 2008-09 since the TGA
is maintained in the Fed’s books. The upsurge in the TGA
balancing arising from the Treasury’s net receipts reserves
drained from the banking system. Also, in the case where there
is an absence of offsetting actions, this would put pressure on
the interest rate of federal funds (Adrian, 2009).
On the other hand, declines in TGA balances as a result of
Treasury net expenditures boosted reserves to the entire banking
system with the consequence that the is a downward pressure on
the federal funds rate stemming from the absence of offsetting
actions. The result of this dynamic is an important interface
between the Fed operations and the Treasury. This interface
required joint management during the crisis and the next section
shows how the Fed and the Treasury jointly managed the
interface from the onset of the financial crisis (Santoro, 2012).
3
The Pre-Crisis Cash Management
The pre-crisis cash management aimed at volatility dampening
of the cash reserves;
To suppress the volatility, the Fed carried out large scale open
market operations (OMO) more frequently;
The key objectives were:
Tax collection;
Stabilizing the TGA balance; and
Generate interest income for the treasury
The Pre-Crisis Cash Management
The cash management prior to the crisis was aimed at volatility
dampening of the cash reserves. This would have been worse if
the Treasury had all the revenues as they came in into the TGA
and if it had held them there up to the time of disbursement. To
suppress the volatility, the Federal Reserve System would have
been forced to carry out large scale open market operations
(OMO) more frequently. The focus would have been to drain
reserves in the instances when TGA balances were diminishing
and increasing reserves when the balances were swelling
(Santoro, 2012). The Treasury sought to maintain a stable
balance in TGA and this worked more efficiently in its Tax and
Loan program.
Before the onset of the crisis the three objectives of cash
management by the treasury under the Tax and Loan program
were to collect federal tax receipts, stabilize the TGA balance,
and to generate (for the Treasury) interest income (Adrian,
2009).
To achieve its tax collection objective, a private deposit-taking
institution could take part in Tax and Loan program by being a
collector institution, a retainer institution, or an investor
institution. As a collector institution, a depository institution
would act as a tax collection conduit to accept tax payments
from corporations and other businesses (basically personal
income withholding taxes, social security contributions, and
corporate taxes) (Santoro, 2012). They would then transfer the
collection to the TGA. As a retainer institution the depository
institutions would still accept the but this would be pegged on
the limit set by the institution and also pledge collateral and
retain the payments in some interest-bearing account up to
such a time that the Treasury would call for them. Any excess
of the Main Account above the set limit would be transferred to
the TGA. As an investor institution, the depository institution
accepted (from Treasury) direct investments and credited them
to the Main Account upon being collateralized (Santoro, 2012).
4
Cash Management by Treasury Following the Onset of the
Crisis
Treasury responded by selling Treasury bills through its
Supplementary Financing Program (SFP);
The was to drain (mop out) excess reserves in the banking
system;
SFP comprised a series of T-bills whose proceeds were
deposited at Fed’s newly created SFP A/c;
Fed’s announcement of beginning to pay interest on the reserves
further led to mop-out.
Cash Management by Treasury Following the Onset of the
Crisis
When the crisis began in 2008, the Treasury made the first
response by selling Treasury bills through its Supplementary
Financing Program (SFP). The consequence of this intervention
was that the reserves were drained from the banking and cut
down the excess reserve volumes. The SFP comprised a series
of T-bills, save for the Treasury’s current borrowing account,
whose purpose was to provide cash to be used for lending and
liquidity initiatives at the Fed. The proceeds for the SFP sales
were deposited at the Fed in the newly created Supplementary
Financing Program account. This initiative succeeded in
draining about $100 billion from the banking system (Adrian,
2009).
Fed announced that it would start paying interest on the reserve
balances. This was aimed at allowing Fed to go on with the
lending program so as to address the credit market conditions
and to keep maintaining the funds rate as the target level, with
or without the SFP. The program resulted into stability up to the
end of the crisis in September 2009 when Treasury embarked on
the redemption of maturing bills. This was done in expectancy
of a debt ceiling constraint.
5
The Treatment of the Financial Crisis
Fed and Treasury applied cash management policies to contain
the crisis;
Policies aimed at cash reserve volatility dampening and price
stability;
OMO enabled Fed to mop out excess reserves during crisis;
This further helped to maintain a stable TGA balance
The Treatment of the Financial Crisis
The treatment of the financial crisis by the Treasury and the Fed
prior and even after can be said to be commendable. Stability of
prices in the economy is a core monetary policy objective and
thus was done prior to the onset of the crisis. The Fed and
Treasury pursued cash management policies that targeted
volatility dampening of the cash reserves (Domar, 2006). If the
cash reserves are allowed to oscillate with wide amplitudes then
this can subject the economy to varied levels of money supply.
The effect of this would be that the prices would vary quite
widely within a short period of time and thus bringing
instability even into the goods prices (Mankiw, 2014).
Applying the monetary policy tools such as OMO to control the
supply of currency was in order. The focus would have been to
drain reserves in the instances when TGA balances were
diminishing and increasing reserves when the balances were
swelling. The Treasury sought to maintain a stable balance in
TGA and this worked more efficiently in its Tax and Loan
program (Mankiw, 2014). This was triggered by the three
objectives at the time that included a continuous tax receipt
flows, stabilization of TGA, and generation of interest income
for the Treasury (Mankiw, 2014).
At the onset of the financial crisis in 2008, the immediate
objective was to drain excess reserve volumes in the banking
system. The Treasury came up with the SFP which worked
effectively through its T-bills. The effect was that the cash to be
used for lending and liquidity initiatives at the Fed was
provided. Effectively, through the SFP about $100 billion was
drained from the banking system thus bringing stability
(Branson, Macroeconomic Theory and practice, 2006).
The announcement by Fed that it would start paying interest on
the reserve balances with an aim of allowing Fed to go on with
the lending program so as to address the credit market
conditions and to keep maintaining the funds rate as the target
level, with or without the SFP was very productive. It resulted
into stability up to the end of the crisis in September 2009 when
Treasury embarked on the redemption of maturing bills. This
intervention was consistent with argument in Mankiw (2014).
6
An Outline the Author’s Arguments
Two approaches key to author's argument
Cash Management: SFP was a management strategy to drain
excess reserves alongside T-bill sales;
Investment Strategy: announcement of increases in interest
payments caused investors to reduce their liquidity holdings
thus further draining excess reserves
An Outline the Author’s Arguments
The author points, basically, at two approaches that worked best
for the Fed in collaboration with the U.S. Treasury in managing
the financial crisis of 2008-09. These are close working
relationship between the Fed and the Treasury in cash
management, and the second one is the manipulation of
investment strategy through compelling T-bill purchase or sales
through raising interest rates.
The SFP was a cash management tool meant to drain reserves
from the banking system so as to reduce overall liquidity in the
economy. This worked effectively to mop up the excess
reserves. By reducing the reserves in the banking system, the
banks were left with fewer funds to give to the people and this
worked to contain the crisis by reducing excess flow of funds.
OMO was the second cash management tool that Santoro (2012)
points out. By selling T-bills to the public and the depository
instituions, the Fed managed to mop out excess liquidity in the
banking system and this helped it in the cash manageemnt.
The second idea fronted Santoro (2012) was that of investment
stratgies. The idea was to announce increases and decreases in
the T-bills rates and retirng of debts. When the Treasury
announced increases in the T-bill rates, the banks and individual
investors purchased more of the T-bills thus reducing the excess
reserves form the banking system. A decrease in the intersest
rates would trigger low demand for the same.
7
References
Adrian, T. C. (2009). The Federal Reserve’s Primary Dealer
Credit Facility: Federal Reserve Bank of New York. Current
Issues in Economics and Finance 15, no. 4 .
Domar, H. (2006). Macroeconomic Theory and Policy. New
York: sage.
Mankiw, G. N. (2014). Principles of Economics 7th Edition.
South-Western College Pub.
Santoro, P. J. (2012). The Evolution of Treasury Cash
Management during the Financial Crisis. current issues in
Economics and Finance Volume 18, Number , 1-11.
cu
rr
en
t
is
su
es
F
E
D
E
R
A
L
R
E
S
E
R
V
E
B
A
N
K
O
F
N
E
W
Y
O
R
K
I
N
E
C
O
N
O
M
I
C
S
A
N
D
F
I
N
A
N
C
E
V
ol
u
m
e
1
8
,
N
u
m
be
r
3
✦
2
0
1
2
✦
w
w
w
.n
ew
yo
rk
fe
d
.o
rg
/r
es
ea
rc
h
/c
u
rr
en
t_
is
su
es
The Evolution of Treasury Cash
Management during the Financial Crisis
Paul J. Santoro
The U.S. Treasury and the Federal Reserve System have long
enjoyed a close relationship, each helping the other to carry
out certain statutory responsibilities. This relationship proved
benefi cial during the 2008-09 fi nancial crisis, when the
Treasury altered its cash management practices to facilitate
the Fed’s dramatic expansion of credit to banks, primary
dealers, and foreign central banks.
L
ike most households and businesses, the U.S. Treasury
maintains a cash
balance to buffer short-run fl uctuations in receipts and
disbursements.
Unlike most households, however, the Treasury’s cash balance
is highly
volatile: between January 1, 2006, and December 31, 2010, it
varied from as little
as $3.1 billion to as much as $188.6 billion (Chart 1).1
The Treasury divides its cash balance between two types of
accounts: a
Treasury General Account (TGA) at the Federal Reserve and
Treasury Tax and
Loan Note accounts (TT&L accounts) at private depository
institutions.2 The
behavior of the respective account balances changed
dramatically in the fall of
2008. As shown in Chart 2, prior to the fi nancial crisis that
followed the collapse
of Lehman Brothers on September 15, 2008 (hereafter, “the
crisis”), the TGA
mostly fl uctuated in a narrow band around $5 billion while
TT&L balances
varied more widely.3 In contrast, since the fall of 2008, TT&L
balances have
fl uctuated in a narrow band around $2 billion and the TGA has
varied widely.
1 We defi ne the Treasury’s cash balance as the difference
between the Total Operating Balance and
the Supplementary Financing Program Account as shown on the
Daily Treasury Statement.
2 The Federal Reserve maintains the TGA as part of its
statutory obligation to serve as fi scal agent
of the United States (Manypenny and Bermudez 1992). The
TGA has existed since January 1916
(1916 Treasury Annual Report, p. 6); TT&L accounts, originally
named “Liberty Loan deposit
accounts,” have existed since May 1917 (Treasury Circular no.
79, May 16, 1917, reprinted
in 1917 Treasury Annual Report, p. 131; Treasury Circular no.
81, May 29, 1917, reprinted in
1917 Treasury Annual Report, p. 124).
3 While the start date of the fi nancial crisis is debatable and
may have been as early as 2007, the
effect of the crisis on Treasury cash management coincided with
the rapid expansion of the Federal
Reserve’s balance sheet after the collapse of Lehman Brothers
in September 2008.
2
CURRENT ISSUES IN ECONOMICS AND FINANCE ❖
Volume 18 Number 3
This edition of Current Issues, one of a group of articles
describing Federal Reserve responses to the crisis,4 explains
how a change in Federal Reserve credit policy during the crisis
was associated with the change in Treasury cash manage-
4 See also Armantier, Krieger, and McAndrews (2008), Adrian,
Burke, and
McAndrews (2009), Fleming, Hrung, and Keane (2009),
Garbade, Keane, Logan,
Stokes, and Wolgemuth (2010), Adrian, Kimbrough, and
Marchioni (2011),
Gagnon, Raskin, Remache, and Sack (2011), and Goldberg,
Kennedy,
and Miu (2011).
ment practices shown in Chart 2. Understanding the relation-
ship between Federal Reserve credit policy and Treasury cash
management is important because the relationship illuminates
an important but sometimes unappreciated interface between the
Treasury and the Fed. It also underscores the symbiotic
relation-
ship between the two institutions, in which each assists the
other
in fulfi lling its statutory responsibilities.
Subsequent sections of this article will detail the changes
in Federal Reserve operating procedures and Treasury cash
Sources: U.S. Department of the Treasury, Daily Treasury
Statement; authors’ calculations.
Note: Cash balances are computed as the difference between the
Total Operating Balance and the Supplementary Financing
Program Account as shown on the Daily
Treasury Statement.
Billions of dollars
2006 2010
Chart 1
Treasury Cash Balances
2007 2008 2009
200
160
120
80
40
0
Source: U.S. Department of the Treasury, Daily Treasury
Statement.
Billions of dollars
2006 2010
Chart 2
Balances in the Treasury General Account and Treasury Tax and
Loan Note Accounts
2007 2008 2009
200
160
120
80
40
Treasury General Account
Treasury Tax and Loan Note accounts
0
management during the crisis. The fi rst section, however,
presents
a framework for the analysis by reviewing the core missions of
the Treasury and the Federal Reserve and explaining how each
institution seeks to fulfi ll its mandate.
The Missions of the U.S. Treasury and the Federal Reserve
The Treasury
A principal mission of the U.S. Treasury is collecting income
taxes and other taxes prescribed by statute and funding the
fi nancial commitments of the U.S. government.5 In the course
of fulfi lling this mandate, the Treasury undertakes a variety of
debt management operations, including refi nancing maturing
debt with new issues, selling additional debt when expenditures
exceed revenues, and retiring debt when the reverse is true. As
noted earlier, the Treasury maintains accounts at the Federal
Reserve and at private depository institutions to buffer day-to-
day
fl uctuations in cash fl ows that cannot be accommodated
effi ciently with debt management operations.
The Federal Reserve
A principal mission of the Federal Reserve System is managing
the U.S. money supply and credit market conditions to promote
maximum employment with stable prices and moderate long-
term interest rates.6 Prior to the fall of 2008, the Fed sought to
carry out this mandate primarily by (1) targeting the interest
rate
on overnight loans in the federal funds market and (2) managing
the supply of reserves available to the banking system to
stabilize
the federal funds rate at the target rate. Offi cials purchased
(sold) Treasury securities, either outright or through repurchase
agreements,7 when they wanted to add (drain) reserves to keep
the funds rate from rising above (falling below) the target.
In the course of responding to the crisis, the Fed provided
unprecedented quantities of central bank credit to banks,
primary dealers, foreign central banks, and others. The increase
in assets on the Fed’s balance sheet generated a corresponding
increase in central bank liabilities. Currency in circulation
expanded modestly, from $835 billion on September 10, 2008,
to $890 billion at the end of the year, but deposits at the central
bank ballooned from $38 billion to $1.2 trillion,8 far beyond
what
depository institutions were required to hold. As described
below,
the Fed and the Treasury adopted a variety of novel procedures
5 See “Duties and Functions of the U.S. Department of the
Treasury,” available
at www.treasury.gov/about/role-of-treasury/Pages/default.aspx.
6 See Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System (2005,
p. 1).
7 A repurchase agreement is a sale of securities coupled with an
agreement to
repurchase the same securities at a specifi ed price on a later
date. Repurchase
agreements are also called “repos.”
8 Deposits at the central bank include reserve balances of
depository institutions,
U.S. Treasury deposits, foreign offi cial deposits, and service-
related deposits
(including required clearing balances and adjustments to
compensate for fl oat).
to prevent the expanding quantity of reserves from driving the
federal funds rate to zero.
The Interface between the Federal Reserve and the Treasury
At fi rst impression, the Federal Reserve and Treasury mandates
might seem suffi ciently distinct that the two institutions should
be able to function independently of each other. However, the
Treasury funnels most of its receipts into, and it disburses most
of its payments from, the TGA. Thus, there is a continuous fl
ow of
funds from private depository institutions to the TGA and back
again. During fi scal year 2010, $11.6 trillion fl owed into, and
then
out of, the TGA.
Flows of funds between the TGA and private depository
institutions were important prior to the crisis because the TGA
is maintained on the books of the Federal Reserve; increases in
TGA balances stemming from Treasury net receipts drained
reserves from the banking system and, in the absence of offset-
ting actions, put upward pressure on the federal funds rate.
Conversely, decreases in TGA balances resulting from Treasury
net expenditures added reserves to the banking system and,
absent offsetting actions, put downward pressure on the funds
rate. This dynamic created an important interface between
Treasury and Federal Reserve operations. The sections that
follow describe fi rst how Treasury and Federal Reserve offi
cials
cooperated to manage the interface before the crisis, and then
how the interface has changed since the onset of the crisis and
the expansion of the Fed’s balance sheet.
Treasury Cash Management before the Crisis
If, in the pre-crisis regime, the Treasury had deposited all of
its receipts in the TGA as soon as they came in, and if it had
held the funds in the TGA until they were disbursed, the supply
of reserves available to the banking system—and hence the
overnight federal funds rate—would have exhibited undesir-
able volatility. To dampen the volatility, the Fed would have
had
to conduct frequent and large-scale open market operations,
draining reserves when TGA balances were declining and add-
ing reserves when TGA balances were rising.9 A more effi cient
strategy, and the one used by the Treasury in its Tax and Loan
program, was to seek to maintain a stable TGA balance.
The Treasury Tax and Loan Program
Prior to the onset of the crisis, the Treasury Tax and Loan
program had three principal objectives: processing federal tax
9 This actually happened between 1974 and 1978. During this
period, the TGA
experienced large fl uctuations when the Treasury sought to
limit aggregate TT&L
balances to about $1.5 billion (Lovett 1978, p. 43), and the
Federal Reserve was
obliged to conduct correspondingly large and frequent open
market operations
(Brockschmidt 1975; McDonough 1976). The need for
aggressive intervention
ended in 1978 following a major reorganization of the TT&L
program (Lovett
1978; Lang 1979).
www.newyorkfed.org/research/cur rent_issues 3
4
CURRENT ISSUES IN ECONOMICS AND FINANCE ❖
Volume 18 Number 3
receipts, stabilizing the TGA balance, and generating interest
income for the Treasury.10
Collecting Federal Tax Receipts
A private depository institution could participate in the TT&L
program in any of three ways: as a collector institution, as a
retainer institution, or as an investor institution.
A collector institution was a tax collection conduit. It accepted
tax payments from businesses (primarily withholdings of per-
sonal income taxes, corporate income taxes, and social security
contributions) in electronic form and at its teller windows and
transferred the payments to the TGA.
A retainer institution also accepted tax payments but, subject
to a limit specifi ed by the institution and pledge of suffi cient
collateral, retained the payments in an interest-bearing “Main
Account” until called for by the Treasury. If a Main Account
balance exceeded the institution’s limit, or if it exceeded the
collateral value of the assets pledged by the institution, the
excess was transferred promptly to the TGA.
An investor institution did everything a retainer institution did
and, as described below, also accepted direct investments from
the Treasury.11 The investments were credited to the
institution’s
Main Account and had to be collateralized.
Stabilizing the TGA Balance
Before the onset of the crisis, the Treasury typically aimed to
maintain a $5 billion balance in the TGA.12 The Treasury used
well-timed cash calls13 and direct investments to maintain the
actual balance close to the target most of the time (see Chart 2).
Each morning Treasury cash managers and analysts at the
Federal Reserve Bank of New York estimated the current day’s
receipts and disbursements. During a telephone conference call
at 9 a.m., they combined the estimates with the previous day’s
closing TGA balance, scheduled payments of principal and
interest, scheduled proceeds from sales of new securities, and
other similar items to produce an estimate of the current day’s
closing balance. If the estimated closing balance exceeded the
target, the Treasury would invest the excess at investor
institutions
10 Garbade, Partlan, and Santoro (2004) describe in more detail
the Treasury Tax
and Loan program as it operated before the crisis. The Treasury
is presently in
the midst of a major revamping of its cash management systems.
See Financial
Management Service, “Collections and Cash Management
Modernization
(CCMM),” available at www.fms.treas.gov/ccmm/index.html.
11 A direct investment was a Treasury-directed transfer of
funds from the TGA
to Treasury’s TT&L accounts at investor banks.
12 The target balance, established in 1988, had to be large
enough to provide a
high degree of confi dence that the TGA would not be
overdrawn at the end of a
business day since the Fed was not authorized to lend directly to
the Treasury.
The target balance was sometimes bumped up to $7 billion when
cash fl ows
were unusually heavy, such as the intervals around tax payment
dates.
13 Cash calls are Treasury-directed transfers from TT&L
accounts to the TGA.
that had suffi cient free collateral and room under their balance
limits to accept additional funds.14 If the estimated balance was
below target, the Treasury would call for funds from retainer
and
investor institutions to make up the shortfall.
Earning Interest on TT&L Balances
The Treasury had three ways to earn interest on TT&L balances.
Conventional Main Account balances earned interest at the
federal funds rate less 25 basis points. In addition, the Treasury
could, at its discretion, make overnight investments in repur-
chase agreements (repos) and term investments through its Term
Investment Option (TIO) program.
The relationship between the rate on Main Account balances
and the federal funds rate was set in 1978, in the course of a
major overhaul of the TT&L program. A market-linked rate
equal
to the funds rate less 25 basis points was deemed appropriate
for collateralized TT&L balances because, at the time, it was
approximately equal to the rate on overnight repurchase agree-
ments on Treasury collateral. However, by the late 1990s, the
spread between the federal funds rate and the repo rate had
narrowed to 5 basis points and the Treasury began to consider
alternatives to obtain a higher rate of return on investments.
The fi rst alternative, the TIO program, was introduced on
an experimental basis in April 2002 and made permanent in
November 2003.15 A TIO auction was similar to a Treasury bill
auction, but in reverse. The Treasury offered to invest (rather
than borrow) a specifi ed amount of money for a specifi ed term
and participating institutions bid on the money. On average
from
March 2006 to March 2007, institutions were willing to pay
about
18 basis points more for TIO balances than they had to pay on
Main Account balances,16 in part because TIO balances would
remain with the institution for a specifi ed term rather than
being subject to daily calls.
In March 2006, the Treasury initiated a pilot program of
investing excess funds through overnight repurchase
agreements.
During the pilot program, the Treasury invested an average of
$2.7 billion per day in repurchase agreements against Treasury
collateral. Daily offerings ranged between $500 million and
$6 billion.17 On average from March 2006 to March 2007,
14 Occasionally, net fl ows into the TGA were so large that the
Treasury exhausted
the capacity of investor institutions to accept additional funds
and TGA balances
rose above the target level by more than several billion dollars.
For more on
stabilizing the TGA and the timing of direct investments and
calls, see, for
example, the discussion of the April 2000 tax payments in
Garbade, Partlan, and
Santoro (2004, p. 6).
15 See, Garbade, Partlan, and Santoro (2004) and Hrung (2007).
16 Government Accountability Offi ce (2007, p. 13, Table 2).
17 U.S. Department of the Treasury, Financial Management
Service, “Repurchase
Agreement (Repo) Program,” available at
http://www.fms.treas.gov/tip/repo/
index.html.
www.newyorkfed.org/research/cur rent_issues 5
institutions were willing to pay about 21 basis points more for
repo balances than they had to pay on Main Account
balances,18
in part for the enhanced certainty of obtaining and retaining
funds until the next business day.
Chart 3 shows how TT&L balances were divided among
conventional Main Account balances, TIO investments, and
repo investments prior to the crisis.
Treasury Cash Management following the Onset
of the Crisis: The Initial Structure
It quickly became clear during the week of September 15, 2008,
that the United States was heading into a major fi nancial crisis.
On Tuesday, September 16, a $63 billion money market mutual
fund “broke the buck” and turned what had been a slow leakage
of shareholder balances into a full-scale run.19 Later the same
day, the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System,
acting
“with the full support of the Treasury Department,” authorized
the Federal Reserve Bank of New York to lend up to $85 billion
to American International Group, Inc. (AIG).20
18 Government Accountability Offi ce (2007, p. 13, Table 2).
19 Investment Company Institute (2009). A money market
mutual fund is said to
break the buck when its net asset value falls below $0.995 per
share. In that case,
the fund has to begin to redeem its shares at net asset value or
otherwise act to
ensure fair treatment of its shareholders.
20 Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, press
release, September 16,
2008; U.S. Department of the Treasury, “Statement by Secretary
Henry M. Paulson,
Jr., on Federal Reserve Actions surrounding AIG,” press
release, September 16, 2008.
By the close of business on Wednesday, September 17,
AIG had borrowed $28 billion, primary dealers had borrowed
$60 billion (through the Primary Dealer Credit Facility21), and
depository institutions had added $10 billion to their discount
window borrowings. In all, Federal Reserve credit expanded by
$100 billion in just two days, and there was more to come.22
As a result of the Fed’s mushrooming loan portfolio, reserve
balances of depository institutions increased from $25 billion
on
September 10 to $82 billion on September 17. It was clear that,
in the absence of profound institutional change, reserve
balances
were going to be vastly in excess of requirements for the
foresee-
able future and federal funds were going to trade well below the
target rate of 2 percent.23
21 Adrian, Burke, and McAndrews (2009) explain the origins
and operation
of the Primary Dealer Credit Facility.
22 On September 18, the Board of Governors announced that it
had agreed
to expand its swap lines with foreign central banks by $180
billion (Board of
Governors of the Federal Reserve System, press release,
September 18, 2008).
Several counterparties promptly expanded their draws of U.S.
dollars by
$64 billion (Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System,
press release,
December 1, 2010). On September 19, the Board announced the
formation of the
Asset-Backed Commercial Paper Money Market Mutual Fund
Liquidity Facility
(Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, press
release, September 19,
2008). The facility opened for business on Monday, September
22, and within
three days lent $73 billion.
23 The Federal Reserve Bank of New York’s annual report of
domestic open
market operations in 2008, prepared by the Bank’s Markets
Group, notes that
“after September 15, [2008], the magnitude of liquidity added to
the system
through various programs exceeded the Federal Reserve’s
ability to offset with
draining operations” (Federal Reserve Bank of New York 2009,
p. 6).
Sources: U.S. Department of the Treasury, Daily Treasury
Statement; authors’ calculations.
Billions of dollars
2006 2007 2008
Chart 3
Allocation of Treasury Tax and Loan Balances among Term
Investment Option Balances, Coventional Main Account
Balances, and Repurchase Agreements prior to September 15,
2008
0
30
60
90
120
150
Term Investment Option balances
Conventional Main Account balances
Repurchase agreements
6
CURRENT ISSUES IN ECONOMICS AND FINANCE ❖
Volume 18 Number 3
The Supplementary Financing Program
The fi rst Treasury cash management change following the onset
of the crisis involved the sale of Treasury bills by the U.S.
Treasury
and the deposit of the proceeds with the Federal Reserve—
actions
that drained reserves from the banking system and reduced the
volume of excess reserves. On Wednesday, September 17, the
Treasury announced the initiation of “a temporary Supple-
mentary Financing Program [SFP] at the request of the Federal
Reserve.”24 The announcement stated that the program would
“consist of a series of Treasury bills, apart from Treasury’s
current
borrowing program, which will provide cash for use in the
Federal Reserve [lending and liquidity] initiatives.” 25 The
Treasury announced three SFP sales that day for a total of
$100 billion. The proceeds from the sales were deposited in a
newly created SFP account at the Fed, thereby draining approxi-
mately $100 billion of reserves from the banking system.
By Friday, October 3, two weeks and two days after the start of
the Supplementary Financing Program, the Treasury had issued
eleven SFP bills (one of which was to refi nance a maturing SFP
bill) and the program had drained about $355 billion of reserve
balances. SFP bills peaked at $560 billion between October 20
and November 12 (Chart 4).
On October 6, the Federal Reserve announced that it would
begin to pay interest on reserve balances effective Thursday,
October 9. This new feature of monetary policy was expected to
allow the Fed to continue to use its lending program to address
conditions in credit markets while also maintaining the funds
rate
close to the target level, even in the absence of the SFP
program. 26
24 U.S. Department of the Treasury, “Treasury Announces
Supplementary
Financing Program,” press release, September 17, 2008.
Emphasis added.
25 The novelty of the SFP program led to some confusion in
describing the
program. The New York Times, for example, reported the fi rst
sale of SFP bills
by stating, “In a sign of how short the Fed’s available reserves
had become, the
Treasury Department sold tens of billions of dollars of special
‘supplementary’
Treasury bills on September 17 to provide the Fed with extra
cash” (“A New Role
for the Fed: Investor of Last Resort,” New York Times,
September 18, 2008, p. A1).
In fact, the Federal Reserve can emit currency and create bank
reserves at will
and thus did not need any “extra cash.” What it could not
fashion from its existing
authorities was a way to drain massive quantities of reserves
from the banking
system. The Wall Street Journal got it right when it stated that
the Treasury was
“carrying out [a reserve] draining function in place of the Fed”
(“U.S. Moves to
Bolster Fed Balance Sheet – Treasury Auctions $40 Billion of
Debt; More Sales
on Tap,” Wall Street Journal, September 18, 2008, p. A3).
26 See Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System,
press release, October 6,
2008: “The payment of interest on excess reserves will permit
the Federal Reserve
to expand its balance sheet as necessary to provide the liquidity
necessary to
support fi nancial stability while implementing the monetary
policy that is
appropriate in light of the System’s macroeconomic objectives
of maximum
employment and price stability.” See also Federal Reserve Bank
of New York
(2009, p. 4): “In theory, the payment of interest on excess
reserve balances allows
the Federal Reserve to continue to use its lending programs to
address conditions
in the credit markets while also maintaining the fed funds rate
close to the target
established by the FOMC.”
On November 17 the Treasury announced that it was
trimming the size of the SFP program.27 By the end of 2008,
there were $260 billion of SFP bills outstanding. The program
stabilized at $200 billion in early March 2009 and remained at
that level until late September 2009, when the Treasury began
to
redeem maturing bills for cash in anticipation of a debt ceiling
constraint.28 The last SFP bill issued in the course of the
original
program was redeemed on December 29, 2009.29
The tenor—or term to maturity—of SFP bills issued in 2008
and 2009 ranged from just 7 days to as many as 101 days in the
fi rst two months of the program, but stabilized at 70 days in
2009 when the overall size of the program fi rmed at $200
billion
(Chart 5). Most SFP bills were issued to refi nance maturing
SFP
bills; in only two instances in 2009 was an SFP bill issued for
new
27 U.S. Department of the Treasury, “Treasury Issues Debt
Management Guidance
on the Temporary Supplementary Financing Program,” press
release, November 17,
2008.
28 See U.S. Department of the Treasury, “Treasury Issues Debt
Management
Guidance on the Supplementary Financing Program, press
release, September 16,
2009; “U.S. Treasury to Scale Back Fed Program to Avoid Debt
Ceiling,” Bloomberg
.com, September 16, 2009; and “Treasury to Shrink Financing
Program,” Wall
Street Journal, September 16, 2009, p. A3.
29 On December 28, 2009, Congress raised the debt ceiling by
$290 billion.
Armed with enlarged issuance authority, the Treasury revived
the Supplementary
Financing Program. The revived program ran from the end of
2009 to mid-2011,
when it was allowed to run down in the face of another debt
ceiling constraint. For
most of that time, the Treasury regularly and predictably
auctioned $25 billion
of eight-week SFP bills every week.
Source: U.S. Department of the Treasury.
Notes: SFP is Supplementary Financing Program. The first
vertical dashed line in the
chart marks the November 17, 2008, announcement by the
Treasury that it would be
reducing the size of the SFP program. The second vertical
dashed line marks the
September 16, 2009, announcement by the Treasury that it
would begin to redeem,
rather than refinance, maturing SFP bills.
Chart 4
SFP Bills Outstanding
Through December 29, 2009
0
100
200
300
400
500
600
Principal amount (billions of dollars)
2008 2009
www.newyorkfed.org/research/cur rent_issues 7
cash. The size of the SFP bills issued in 2008 and 2009 initially
ranged from $30 billion to $60 billion, but stabilized at $30
billion
to $35 billion in 2009 (Chart 6).
Treasury Cash Management after the Fed Began
Paying Interest on Reserves
On October 6, 2008, when the Federal Reserve announced that
it would begin to pay interest on reserves, it stated that it would
pay the average target federal funds rate over a reserve main-
tenance period, less 10 basis points, on required reserves and
the lowest target rate over a maintenance period, less 75 basis
points, on excess reserves.30 Following several changes in the
target funds rate and the rate paid on required reserve balances
and excess balances, the FOMC established (on December 16,
2008) a target range of zero to 25 basis points for the funds
rate,
and the Board of Governors announced a rate of 25 basis points
on reserve balances.31 (The rate of interest on excess reserves
is
commonly known as the “IOER rate.”) Charts 7 and 8 show that
the federal funds rate was persistently below the IOER rate
from
late 2008 through 2010.
Consequences for Treasury Cash Management
The structure of interest rates after December 2008 prompted
the Treasury to make a second change in its cash management
practices since it now had an economic incentive to keep its
cash balances in the Treasury General Account rather than in
Treasury Tax and Loan Note accounts. When the overnight
federal funds rate fell below 25 basis points, the TT&L rate
on Main Account balances went to zero and the likely rates of
30 Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, press
release, October 6, 2008.
31 Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, press
release, December 16,
2008.
Source: U.S. Department of the Treasury.
Note: SFP is Supplementary Financing Program.
Chart 5
Tenor of SFP Bills Issued in 2008 and 2009
0
30
60
90
120
Number of days
2008 2009
Date of issue
Source: U.S. Department of the Treasury.
Note: SFP is Supplementary Financing Program.
Chart 6
Size of SFP Bills Issued in 2008 and 2009
0
25
50
75
Principal amount (billions of SFP dollars)
2008 2009
Date of issue
Sources: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System;
Federal Reserve Bank
of New York.
Notes: IOER is the interest rate on excess reserves. Days
marked on the horizontal axis
denote the beginnings of reserve maintenance periods.
Chart 7
Target Federal Funds Rate, IOER Rate,
and Federal Funds Rate
Percent
0
0.5
1.0
1.5
2.0
2.5
3.0
Au
gu
st
2
8
2008
Federal funds rate
Target federal funds rate
(or upper end of target range)
IOER rate
(when different from target
federal funds rate)
Se
pt
em
be
r 1
1
Se
pt
em
be
r 2
5
Oc
to
be
r 9
Oc
to
be
r 2
3
No
ve
m
be
r 6
No
ve
m
be
r 2
0
De
ce
m
be
r 4
De
ce
m
be
r 1
8
Ja
nu
ar
y 1
2009
8
CURRENT ISSUES IN ECONOMICS AND FINANCE ❖
Volume 18 Number 3
interest on TIO balances and Treasury repurchase agreements
fell
below 25 basis points. In that environment, it was more remu-
nerative for the Treasury to keep its money in the TGA. Shifting
Treasury balances to private depositories would have increased
the reserve balances of depository institutions and required the
Fed to pay interest on those reserve balances (at the IOER rate
of 25 basis points per annum). This would have reduced Federal
Reserve payments to the Treasury (of Federal Reserve earnings
in excess of expenses) by more than what the Treasury could
earn
from the depositories.32 In addition, a large TGA balance
limited
the risk that the Treasury might overdraw the account at a time
when expenditures were extraordinarily volatile.
At the same time, the volatile swings in TGA balances associ-
ated with the decision to keep essentially all of the Treasury’s
operating cash balances in the TGA (see Chart 2) did not cause
a problem for the Fed because the swings did not result in any
comparable volatility in the federal funds rate. In particular,
expanding TGA balances did not reduce the quantity of reserves
available to the banking system to a level at all close to what
banks wanted or were required to hold and thus did not put
upward pressure on the funds rate.
Consequences for the Supplementary Financing Program
In principle, paying interest on reserves could have led the
Treasury to terminate the Supplementary Financing Program.
Adhering to its November 17, 2008, announcement, the
Treasury
32 However, the Treasury continued to keep $2 billion in TT&L
accounts until
December 29, 2011, to ensure that the functionalities of the
TT&L program
remained intact in the event that the Fed returned to the pre-
crisis structure of
monetary policy. By 2012, collector and retainer designations
were eliminated, and
the TT&L investment program was shut down. Treasury
indicated that it planned
on implementing a new investment program when market
conditions warranted
and that more details would be announced when they became
available.
did reduce the size of the program, but it did not eliminate it
entirely (Chart 4).
There were several reasons for not eliminating the Supple-
mentary Financing Program at the end of 2008. First, SFP bills
soaked up a nontrivial quantity of excess reserves.33 Second,
higher SFP balances, like higher TGA balances, reduced the
volume of reserves on which the Federal Reserve had to pay
interest and were, therefore, fiscally beneficial to the Treasury.
And third, the Supplementary Financing Program provided
market participants with additional quantities of a short-term,
credit risk–free instrument that was unusually attractive in
the midst of the crisis.34
Conclusion
The Treasury Tax and Loan Note program has long been an
exemplar of cooperation between the Federal Reserve and the
Treasury, with the Fed serving as the Treasury’s fi scal agent
in maintaining the Treasury General Account and with the
Treasury issuing cash calls and making direct investments to
stabilize the TGA at a specifi ed target level. The 2008-09 crisis
triggered a further deepening of the close relationship between
the two institutions. When the Fed’s balance sheet ballooned
in September 2008 as the crisis deepened, the Treasury
announced, at the Fed’s request, the Supplementary Financ-
ing Program to soak up excess reserves and to keep the federal
funds rate from being driven down to zero. The subsequent
introduction of interest on reserves left the Treasury free to
abandon those aspects of the TT&L program aimed at stabi-
lizing the TGA and allowed it to pursue cash management
practices that, in light of the new monetary regime, were in
the best interest of taxpayers.
The Treasury’s cash management and investment strategy
continues to evolve, guided by the goals of earning a fair return
on investment, ensuring that the funds available in the TGA are
suffi cent to avoid an overdraft, and avoiding interference with
the
implementation of monetary policy. When the interest rates that
the Treasury receives on investments are higher, it may resume
investing its surplus funds with the private sector, as it did prior
to 2009. However, if short-term interest rates remain close to
cur-
rent levels and there is no need to target the TGA, then Treasury
investments are likely to remain low or nonexistent since
holding
funds in the TGA is more remunerative than investing funds
with
the private sector.
Nevertheless, a signifi cant decline in excess reserves resulting
from a shift in monetary policy may once again make it
necessary
to target a more stable TGA, so that TGA volatility does not
cause
33 Bernanke (2009) observed that “issuance of [SFP] bills
effectively drains
reserves from the banking system, improving monetary control.”
34 Hrung and Seligman (2011, p. 7) noted that “an incidental
by-product” of the
SFP program “was that it increased the amount of high-quality
collateral
available in the market, helping to alleviate . . . supply-side
stresses in the
money markets. . . .”
Sources: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System;
Federal Reserve Bank
of New York.
Note: The IOER rate is the interest rate on excess reserves.
Chart 8
IOER Rate and Federal Funds Rate
Percent
IOER rate
Federal funds rate
0
0.05
0.10
0.15
0.20
0.25
0.30
0.35
20102009
www.newyorkfed.org/research/cur rent_issues 9
undesirable federal funds rate volatility and interfere with the
implementation of monetary policy.
The author thanks Kenneth Garbade for his many substantive
contributions to the preparation of this article. He also thanks
David Monroe, Warren Hrung, John Partlan, Gregory Till, and
Chris Burke for helpful comments on earlier versions.
References
Adrian, Tobias, Christopher Burke, and James McAndrews.
2009. “The Federal
Reserve’s Primary Dealer Credit Facility.” Federal Reserve
Bank of New York
Current Issues in Economics and Finance 15, no. 4 (August).
Adrian, Tobias, Karin Kimbrough, and Dina Marchioni. 2011.
“The Federal
Reserve’s Commercial Paper Funding Facility.” Federal Reserve
Bank of New York
Economic Policy Review 17, no. 1 (May): 25-39.
Armantier, Olivier, Sandra Krieger, and James McAndrews.
2008. “The Federal
Reserve’s Term Auction Facility.” Federal Reserve Bank of
New York Current Issues
in Economics and Finance 14, no. 5 (July).
Bernanke, Ben. 2009. The Crisis and the Policy Response.
Stamp Lecture,
London School of Economics, London, England, January 13.
Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. 2005. The
Federal Reserve
System: Purposes and Functions.
Brockschmidt, Peggy. 1975. “Treasury Cash Balances.” Federal
Reserve Bank
of Kansas City Monthly Review 60, no. 7 (July-August): 12-20.
Federal Reserve Bank of New York. 2009. Domestic Open
Market Operations
during 2008. Available at
www.newyorkfed.org/markets/omo/omo2008.pdf.
Fleming, Michael, Warren Hrung, and Frank Keane. 2009. “The
Term Securities
Lending Facility: Origin, Design, and Effects.” Federal Reserve
Bank of New York
Current Issues in Economics and Finance 15, no. 2 (February).
Gagnon, Joseph, Matthew Raskin, Julie Remache, and Brian
Sack. “Large-Scale
Asset Purchases by the Federal Reserve: Did They Work?”
Federal Reserve Bank
of New York Economic Policy Review 17, no. 1 (May): 41-59.
The views expressed in this article are those of the authors and
do not necessarily refl ect the position
of the Federal Reserve Bank of New York or the Federal
Reserve System.
Current Issues in Economics and Finance is published by the
Research and Statistics Group of the Federal Reserve Bank of
New York.
Linda Goldberg and Thomas Klitgaard are the editors.
Editorial Staff: Valerie LaPorte, Mike De Mott, Michelle Bailer,
Karen Carter, Anna Snider
Production: Carol Perlmutter, David Rosenberg, Jane Urry
Subscriptions to Current Issues are free. Send an e-mail to
[email protected] or write to the Publications Function,
Federal Reserve Bank of New York, 33 Liberty Street, New
York, N.Y. 10045-0001. Back issues of Current Issues are
available
at http://www.newyorkfed.org/research/current_issues/.
ABOUT THE AUTHORS
Paul J. Santoro is a senior fi nancial/economic analyst in the
Market Operations, Monitoring, and Analysis Function of the
Federal Reserve Bank of New York’s Markets Group.
Garbade, Kenneth, Frank Keane, Lorie Logan, Amanda Stokes,
and Jennifer
Wolgemuth. 2010. “The Introduction of the TMPG Fails Charge
for U.S. Treasury
Securities.” Federal Reserve Bank of New York Economic
Policy Review 16, no. 2
(October): 45-71.
Garbade, Kenneth, John Partlan, and Paul Santoro. 2004.
“Recent Innovations in
Treasury Cash Management.” Federal Reserve Bank of New
York Current Issues
in Economics and Finance 10, no. 11 (November).
Goldberg, Linda, Craig Kennedy, and Jason Miu. 2011. “Central
Bank Dollar Swap
Lines and Overseas Dollar Funding Costs.” Federal Reserve
Bank of New York
Economic Policy Review 17, no. 1 (May): 3-20.
Government Accountability Offi ce. 2007. Debt Management:
Treasury Has
Improved Short-Term Investment Programs, but Should Broaden
Investments
to Reduce Risks and Increase Returns. GAO-07-1105.
Hrung, Warren. 2007. “An Examination of Treasury Term
Investment Interest
Rates.” Federal Reserve Bank of New York Economic Policy
Review 13, no. 1
(March): 19-32.
Hrung, Warren, and Jason Seligman. 2011. “Responses to the
Financial Crisis,
Treasury Debt, and the Impact on Short-Term Money Markets.”
Federal Reserve
Bank of New York Staff Reports, no. 481, January.
Investment Company Institute. 2009. Report of the Money
Market Working Group.
Lang, Richard. 1979. “TTL Note Accounts and the Money
Supply Process.”
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Review 61, no. 1 (October):
3-14.
Lovett, Joan. 1978. “Treasury Tax and Loan Accounts and
Federal Reserve Open
Market Operations.” Federal Reserve Bank of New York
Quarterly Review 3,
no. 2 (summer): 41-6.
Manypenny, Gerald D., and Michael L. Bermudez. 1992. “The
Federal Reserve
Banks as Fiscal Agents and Depositories of the United States.”
Federal Reserve
Bulletin 78, no. 10 (October): 727-37.
McDonough, William. 1976. “New Policy Prompts Increased
Defensive
Operations by Federal Reserve.” Federal Reserve Bank of
Dallas Business
Review, March: 8-12.
Special Inspector General for the Troubled Asset Relief
Program. 2009. Initial
Report to the Congress, February 6.
10
CURRENT ISSUES IN ECONOMICS AND FINANCE ❖
Volume 18 Number 3
RELATED READINGS FROM THE FEDERAL RESERVE
BANK OF NEW YORK’S RESEARCH GROUP
Articles and Papers
The Federal Reserve’s Commercial Paper Funding Facility
Tobias Adrian, Karin Kimbrough, and Dina Marchioni
Economic Policy Review, vol. 17, no. 1, May 2011
Established in the wake of Lehman Brothers’ bankruptcy to
stabilize severe disruptions in the commercial paper market, the
Commercial Paper Funding Facility allowed the Federal Reserve
to act as a lender of last resort for issuers of commercial paper,
thereby effectively addressing temporary liquidity distortions
and alleviating the severe funding stress that threatened to
further exacerbate the fi nancial crisis. In doing so, the facility
proved to be a noteworthy model of liquidity provision in a
market-based fi nancial system, where maturity transformation
occurs outside of the commercial banking sector. This study
examines the creation and performance of the facility, while
outlining the evolution and importance of the commercial
paper market.
The Federal Reserve’s Primary Dealer Credit Facility
Tobias Adrian, Christopher Burke, and James McAndrews
Current Issues in Economics and Finance, vol. 15, no. 4, August
2009
As liquidity conditions in the “repo market”—the market where
broker-dealers obtain fi nancing for their securities—deterio-
rated following the near-bankruptcy of Bear Stearns in March
2008, the Federal Reserve took the step of creating a special
facility to provide overnight loans to dealers that have a trading
relationship with the Federal Reserve Bank of New York. Six
months later, in the wake of new strains in the repo market, the
Fed expanded the facility by broadening the types of collateral
accepted for loans. Both initiatives were designed to help
restore
the orderly functioning of the market and to prevent the spill-
over of distress to other fi nancial fi rms.
The Term Securities Lending Facility: Origin, Design,
and Effects
Michael Fleming, Warren Hrung, and Frank Keane
Current Issues in Economics and Finance, vol. 15, no. 2,
February 2009
The Federal Reserve launched the Term Securities Lending
Facility (TSLF) in 2008 to promote liquidity in the funding
markets and improve the operation of the broader fi nancial
markets. The facility increases the ability of dealers to obtain
cash in the private market by enabling them to pledge securities
temporarily as collateral for Treasuries, which are relatively
easy
to fi nance. The TSLF thus reduces the need for dealers to sell
assets into illiquid markets and lessens the likelihood of a loss
of confi dence among lenders.
The Federal Reserve’s Term Auction Facility
Olivier Armantier, Sandra Krieger, and James McAndrews
Current Issues in Economics and Finance, vol. 14, no. 5, July
2008
As liquidity conditions in the term funding markets grew
increasingly
strained in late 2007, the Federal Reserve began making funds
avail-
able directly to banks through a new tool, the Term Auction
Facility
(TAF). The TAF provides term funding on a collateralized
basis, at
interest rates and amounts set by auction. The facility is
designed to
improve liquidity by making it easier for sound institutions to
borrow
when the markets are not operating effi ciently.
Large-Scale Asset Purchases by the Federal Reserve:
Did They Work?
Joseph Gagnon, Matthew Raskin, Julie Remache, and Brian
Sack
Economic Policy Review, vol. 17, no. 1, May 2011
This study reviews the Federal Reserve’s experience in imple-
menting large-scale asset purchases between late 2008 and
March 2010. The authors show that by reducing the net supply
of assets with long maturities, the purchases led to economi-
cally meaningful and long-lasting reductions in longer term
interest rates on a range of securities. The reductions primarily
refl ect lower risk premiums, including term premiums. The
asset
purchase programs had an especially powerful effect on longer
term interest rates on agency debt and agency mortgage-backed
securities by improving market liquidity and removing assets
with high prepayment risk from private portfolios.
The Introduction of the TMPG Fails Charge
for U.S. Treasury Securities
Kenneth Garbade, Frank Keane, Lorie Logan, Amanda Stokes,
and Jennifer Wolgemuth
Economic Policy Review, vol. 16, no. 2, October 2010
The TPMG fails charge for U.S. Treasury securities provides
that
a buyer of Treasury securities can claim monetary compensa-
tion from the seller if the seller fails to deliver the securities
on a timely basis. The charge was introduced in May 2009 and
replaced an existing market convention of simply postpon-
ing—without any explicit penalty and at an unchanged invoice
price—a seller’s obligation to deliver Treasury securities of the
seller fails to deliver the securities on a scheduled settlement
date. This article explains how a proliferation of settlement
fails following the insolvency of Lehman Brothers Holdings
Inc.
in September 2008 led the Treasury Market Practices Group
(TPMG), a group of market professionals committed to sup-
porting the integrity and effi ciency of the U.S. Treasury
market,
to promote a change in the existing market convention. The
change—the introduction of the fails charge—was signifi cant
www.newyorkfed.org/research/cur rent_issues 11
because it mitigated an important dysfunctionality in the
secondary market for U.S. Treasury securities and because it
stands as an example of the value of cooperation between the
public and private sectors in responding to altered market
conditions in a fl exible, timely, and innovative fashion.
Recent Innovations in Treasury Cash Management
Kenneth Garbade, John Partlan, and Paul Santoro
Current Issues in Economics and Finance, vol. 10, no. 11,
November 2004
The Treasury Tax and Loan program, a joint undertaking of
the Treasury and the Federal Reserve, is designed to manage
federal tax receipts and stabilize the supply of reserves in the
banking system. Three recent innovations—electronic collec-
tion of business taxes, real-time investment of excess Treasury
balances, and competitive bidding for Treasury deposits—have
materially enhanced the ability of the two agencies to achieve
these objectives.
An Examination of Treasury Term Investment Interest Rates
Warren Hrung
Economic Policy Review, vol. 13, no. 1, March 2007
In November 2003, the Term Investment Option (TIO) program
became an offi cial cash management tool of the U.S. Treasury
Department. Through TIO, the Treasury lends funds to banks
for a set number of days at an interest rate determined by a
single-rate auction. One reason why the Treasury introduced
TIO was to try to earn a market rate of return on its excess cash
balances. This article studies 166 TIO auctions from November
2003 to February 2006 to determine how TIO interest rates have
compared with market rates. The author investigates the spread
between TIO rates and rates on mortgage-backed-security
repos, a close benchmark for TIO rates. He fi nds that aside
from
offerings with very short-term lengths, the Treasury receives an
interest rate on TIO auctions comparable to market rates. He
also documents a negative relationship between an auction’s
size and the spread between TIO and repo rates. Furthermore,
the Treasury’s announcement and auctioning of funds on the
same day does not adversely affect rate spreads, a fi nding that
suggests that banks are indifferent to more advance notice of
TIO auctions.
Responses to the Financial Crisis, Treasury Debt, and
the Impact on Short-Term Money Markets
Warren Hrung and Jason Seligman
Staff Reports, no. 481, January 2011
Several programs have been introduced by U.S. fi scal and
monetary authorities in response to the fi nancial crisis. This
study examines the responses involving Treasury debt—the
Term Securities Lending Facility (TSLF), the Supplemental
Financing Program, increases in Treasury issuance, and open
market operations—and their impacts on the overnight Treasury
general collateral repo rate, a key money market rate. The
authors’
contribution is to consider each policy in light of the others,
both
to help guide policy responses to future crises and to empha-
size policy interactions. Only the TSLF was designed to directly
address stresses in short-term money markets by temporarily
changing the supply of Treasury collateral in the marketplace.
We fi nd that the TSLF is uniquely effective relative to other
policies and that, while changes in Treasury collateral do affect
repo rates, the impacts are not equivalent across sources of
Treasury collateral.
Central Bank Dollar Swap Lines and Overseas Dollar
Funding Costs
Linda Goldberg, Craig Kennedy, and Jason Miu
Economic Policy Review, vol. 17, no. 1, May 2011
In the decade prior to the fi nancial crisis, foreign banks’
exposure
to U.S.-dollar-denominated assets increased dramatically. When
the crisis hit in 2007, the banks’ access to dollar funding came
under severe constraints. The Federal Reserve responded in
December 2007 by establishing temporary reciprocal currency
swap lines with foreign central banks designed to ameliorate the
dollar funding stresses overseas. Drawing on rigorous analysis
of the swaps, as well as insights of other economic studies and
anecdotal accounts of market participants, this article concludes
that the lines were effective in reducing both dollar funding
costs
abroad and stresses in the money markets.
Liberty Street Economics Blog Posts
Innovations in Treasury Debt Instruments
Kenneth Garbade
April 9, 2012
Will “Quantitative Easing” Trigger Infl ation?
Kenneth Garbade
June 8, 2011
Will the Federal Reserve’s Asset Purchases Lead to
Higher Infl ation?
Jamie McAndrews
May 18, 2011

More Related Content

Similar to Macroeconomics NameCourseInstructorInstitutio.docx

Financial Liberalisation and Economic Growth In Nigeria: An Empirical Analysis
Financial Liberalisation and Economic Growth In Nigeria: An Empirical AnalysisFinancial Liberalisation and Economic Growth In Nigeria: An Empirical Analysis
Financial Liberalisation and Economic Growth In Nigeria: An Empirical Analysisiosrjce
 
IMF: Global Financial Stability Report (April 2020)
IMF: Global Financial Stability Report (April 2020)IMF: Global Financial Stability Report (April 2020)
IMF: Global Financial Stability Report (April 2020)TatianaApostolovich
 
Presentation1
Presentation1Presentation1
Presentation1lespayos
 
Fiscal policy of europe
Fiscal policy of europeFiscal policy of europe
Fiscal policy of europeNits Kedia
 
Financial repression Mr Setonga, Mzumbe University Tanzania- Morogoro
Financial repression Mr Setonga, Mzumbe University Tanzania- MorogoroFinancial repression Mr Setonga, Mzumbe University Tanzania- Morogoro
Financial repression Mr Setonga, Mzumbe University Tanzania- Morogorojaycejay
 
conducting monetary policy
conducting monetary policyconducting monetary policy
conducting monetary policyeid abuirmaileh
 
Соглашение Республики Молдова с МВФ 2016 год ноябрь
Соглашение Республики Молдова с МВФ 2016 год ноябрьСоглашение Республики Молдова с МВФ 2016 год ноябрь
Соглашение Республики Молдова с МВФ 2016 год ноябрьprivate
 
Read the article, and write 6-7 pages reviews.These are the sugg.docx
Read the article, and write 6-7 pages reviews.These are the sugg.docxRead the article, and write 6-7 pages reviews.These are the sugg.docx
Read the article, and write 6-7 pages reviews.These are the sugg.docxcatheryncouper
 
2008 Global CrisisStarting in 2005, the Federal Reserve perc.docx
2008 Global CrisisStarting in 2005, the Federal Reserve perc.docx2008 Global CrisisStarting in 2005, the Federal Reserve perc.docx
2008 Global CrisisStarting in 2005, the Federal Reserve perc.docxdomenicacullison
 
1PAGE 3CTW2David GijonGeorgia State University.docx
1PAGE  3CTW2David GijonGeorgia State University.docx1PAGE  3CTW2David GijonGeorgia State University.docx
1PAGE 3CTW2David GijonGeorgia State University.docxeugeniadean34240
 
What is the theory of public debt managementSolution1. Sove.pdf
What is the theory of public debt managementSolution1. Sove.pdfWhat is the theory of public debt managementSolution1. Sove.pdf
What is the theory of public debt managementSolution1. Sove.pdfJUSTSTYLISH3B2MOHALI
 
The impact of interest rates on the development of an emerging market empiric...
The impact of interest rates on the development of an emerging market empiric...The impact of interest rates on the development of an emerging market empiric...
The impact of interest rates on the development of an emerging market empiric...Alexander Decker
 
Final fiscal sustainability up_mla_gil_b
Final fiscal sustainability up_mla_gil_bFinal fiscal sustainability up_mla_gil_b
Final fiscal sustainability up_mla_gil_brbulalakaw
 

Similar to Macroeconomics NameCourseInstructorInstitutio.docx (18)

Financial Liberalisation and Economic Growth In Nigeria: An Empirical Analysis
Financial Liberalisation and Economic Growth In Nigeria: An Empirical AnalysisFinancial Liberalisation and Economic Growth In Nigeria: An Empirical Analysis
Financial Liberalisation and Economic Growth In Nigeria: An Empirical Analysis
 
UCMP.pptx
UCMP.pptxUCMP.pptx
UCMP.pptx
 
IMF: Global Financial Stability Report (April 2020)
IMF: Global Financial Stability Report (April 2020)IMF: Global Financial Stability Report (April 2020)
IMF: Global Financial Stability Report (April 2020)
 
Presentation1
Presentation1Presentation1
Presentation1
 
Fiscal policy of europe
Fiscal policy of europeFiscal policy of europe
Fiscal policy of europe
 
3. soto and youssef
3. soto and youssef3. soto and youssef
3. soto and youssef
 
Financial repression Mr Setonga, Mzumbe University Tanzania- Morogoro
Financial repression Mr Setonga, Mzumbe University Tanzania- MorogoroFinancial repression Mr Setonga, Mzumbe University Tanzania- Morogoro
Financial repression Mr Setonga, Mzumbe University Tanzania- Morogoro
 
Monetary policy
Monetary policyMonetary policy
Monetary policy
 
conducting monetary policy
conducting monetary policyconducting monetary policy
conducting monetary policy
 
Соглашение Республики Молдова с МВФ 2016 год ноябрь
Соглашение Республики Молдова с МВФ 2016 год ноябрьСоглашение Республики Молдова с МВФ 2016 год ноябрь
Соглашение Республики Молдова с МВФ 2016 год ноябрь
 
Read the article, and write 6-7 pages reviews.These are the sugg.docx
Read the article, and write 6-7 pages reviews.These are the sugg.docxRead the article, and write 6-7 pages reviews.These are the sugg.docx
Read the article, and write 6-7 pages reviews.These are the sugg.docx
 
2008 Global CrisisStarting in 2005, the Federal Reserve perc.docx
2008 Global CrisisStarting in 2005, the Federal Reserve perc.docx2008 Global CrisisStarting in 2005, the Federal Reserve perc.docx
2008 Global CrisisStarting in 2005, the Federal Reserve perc.docx
 
1PAGE 3CTW2David GijonGeorgia State University.docx
1PAGE  3CTW2David GijonGeorgia State University.docx1PAGE  3CTW2David GijonGeorgia State University.docx
1PAGE 3CTW2David GijonGeorgia State University.docx
 
What is the theory of public debt managementSolution1. Sove.pdf
What is the theory of public debt managementSolution1. Sove.pdfWhat is the theory of public debt managementSolution1. Sove.pdf
What is the theory of public debt managementSolution1. Sove.pdf
 
Update Seminar
Update SeminarUpdate Seminar
Update Seminar
 
The impact of interest rates on the development of an emerging market empiric...
The impact of interest rates on the development of an emerging market empiric...The impact of interest rates on the development of an emerging market empiric...
The impact of interest rates on the development of an emerging market empiric...
 
Final fiscal sustainability up_mla_gil_b
Final fiscal sustainability up_mla_gil_bFinal fiscal sustainability up_mla_gil_b
Final fiscal sustainability up_mla_gil_b
 
success and failures of imf
success and failures of imfsuccess and failures of imf
success and failures of imf
 

More from infantsuk

Please cite and include references- Broderick & Blewitt (2015) must.docx
Please cite and include references- Broderick & Blewitt (2015) must.docxPlease cite and include references- Broderick & Blewitt (2015) must.docx
Please cite and include references- Broderick & Blewitt (2015) must.docxinfantsuk
 
Please choose 1 of the 2 topics below for this weeks assignment.docx
Please choose 1 of the 2 topics below for this weeks assignment.docxPlease choose 1 of the 2 topics below for this weeks assignment.docx
Please choose 1 of the 2 topics below for this weeks assignment.docxinfantsuk
 
Please be advised that for the second writing assignment, the clas.docx
Please be advised that for the second writing assignment, the clas.docxPlease be advised that for the second writing assignment, the clas.docx
Please be advised that for the second writing assignment, the clas.docxinfantsuk
 
Please briefly describe cross cultural variations in Consumer Beha.docx
Please briefly describe cross cultural variations in Consumer Beha.docxPlease briefly describe cross cultural variations in Consumer Beha.docx
Please briefly describe cross cultural variations in Consumer Beha.docxinfantsuk
 
Please be sure to organize your report using section headers to clea.docx
Please be sure to organize your report using section headers to clea.docxPlease be sure to organize your report using section headers to clea.docx
Please be sure to organize your report using section headers to clea.docxinfantsuk
 
Please attach two different assignments. Please first provide the dr.docx
Please attach two different assignments. Please first provide the dr.docxPlease attach two different assignments. Please first provide the dr.docx
Please attach two different assignments. Please first provide the dr.docxinfantsuk
 
Please answers some questions below (attached references)  1.Wh.docx
Please answers some questions below (attached references)  1.Wh.docxPlease answers some questions below (attached references)  1.Wh.docx
Please answers some questions below (attached references)  1.Wh.docxinfantsuk
 
Please answer these discussion questions thoroughly.  Provide re.docx
Please answer these discussion questions thoroughly.  Provide re.docxPlease answer these discussion questions thoroughly.  Provide re.docx
Please answer these discussion questions thoroughly.  Provide re.docxinfantsuk
 
Please click on this link and follow the directions to complete the .docx
Please click on this link and follow the directions to complete the .docxPlease click on this link and follow the directions to complete the .docx
Please click on this link and follow the directions to complete the .docxinfantsuk
 
Please choose one of the following questions, and post your resp.docx
Please choose one of the following questions, and post your resp.docxPlease choose one of the following questions, and post your resp.docx
Please choose one of the following questions, and post your resp.docxinfantsuk
 
Please answer the questions in paragraphs containing at least fi.docx
Please answer the questions in paragraphs containing at least fi.docxPlease answer the questions in paragraphs containing at least fi.docx
Please answer the questions in paragraphs containing at least fi.docxinfantsuk
 
Please answer the following three questions in one to two paragraphs.docx
Please answer the following three questions in one to two paragraphs.docxPlease answer the following three questions in one to two paragraphs.docx
Please answer the following three questions in one to two paragraphs.docxinfantsuk
 
Please answer the following1.  Transformational leadership and .docx
Please answer the following1.  Transformational leadership and .docxPlease answer the following1.  Transformational leadership and .docx
Please answer the following1.  Transformational leadership and .docxinfantsuk
 
Please answer the below questionDescribe social bandwidth and s.docx
Please answer the below questionDescribe social bandwidth and s.docxPlease answer the below questionDescribe social bandwidth and s.docx
Please answer the below questionDescribe social bandwidth and s.docxinfantsuk
 
Please answer the following questions1.- Please name the fu.docx
Please answer the following questions1.- Please name the fu.docxPlease answer the following questions1.- Please name the fu.docx
Please answer the following questions1.- Please name the fu.docxinfantsuk
 
Please answer the following questions1.- Please name the follow.docx
Please answer the following questions1.- Please name the follow.docxPlease answer the following questions1.- Please name the follow.docx
Please answer the following questions1.- Please name the follow.docxinfantsuk
 
Please answer the following questions with supporting examples and f.docx
Please answer the following questions with supporting examples and f.docxPlease answer the following questions with supporting examples and f.docx
Please answer the following questions with supporting examples and f.docxinfantsuk
 
Please answer the following questions about air and water pollution .docx
Please answer the following questions about air and water pollution .docxPlease answer the following questions about air and water pollution .docx
Please answer the following questions about air and water pollution .docxinfantsuk
 
please answer the following 7 questions in its entirety.  #11.C.docx
please answer the following 7 questions in its entirety.  #11.C.docxplease answer the following 7 questions in its entirety.  #11.C.docx
please answer the following 7 questions in its entirety.  #11.C.docxinfantsuk
 
Please answer the questions listed below and submit in a word docume.docx
Please answer the questions listed below and submit in a word docume.docxPlease answer the questions listed below and submit in a word docume.docx
Please answer the questions listed below and submit in a word docume.docxinfantsuk
 

More from infantsuk (20)

Please cite and include references- Broderick & Blewitt (2015) must.docx
Please cite and include references- Broderick & Blewitt (2015) must.docxPlease cite and include references- Broderick & Blewitt (2015) must.docx
Please cite and include references- Broderick & Blewitt (2015) must.docx
 
Please choose 1 of the 2 topics below for this weeks assignment.docx
Please choose 1 of the 2 topics below for this weeks assignment.docxPlease choose 1 of the 2 topics below for this weeks assignment.docx
Please choose 1 of the 2 topics below for this weeks assignment.docx
 
Please be advised that for the second writing assignment, the clas.docx
Please be advised that for the second writing assignment, the clas.docxPlease be advised that for the second writing assignment, the clas.docx
Please be advised that for the second writing assignment, the clas.docx
 
Please briefly describe cross cultural variations in Consumer Beha.docx
Please briefly describe cross cultural variations in Consumer Beha.docxPlease briefly describe cross cultural variations in Consumer Beha.docx
Please briefly describe cross cultural variations in Consumer Beha.docx
 
Please be sure to organize your report using section headers to clea.docx
Please be sure to organize your report using section headers to clea.docxPlease be sure to organize your report using section headers to clea.docx
Please be sure to organize your report using section headers to clea.docx
 
Please attach two different assignments. Please first provide the dr.docx
Please attach two different assignments. Please first provide the dr.docxPlease attach two different assignments. Please first provide the dr.docx
Please attach two different assignments. Please first provide the dr.docx
 
Please answers some questions below (attached references)  1.Wh.docx
Please answers some questions below (attached references)  1.Wh.docxPlease answers some questions below (attached references)  1.Wh.docx
Please answers some questions below (attached references)  1.Wh.docx
 
Please answer these discussion questions thoroughly.  Provide re.docx
Please answer these discussion questions thoroughly.  Provide re.docxPlease answer these discussion questions thoroughly.  Provide re.docx
Please answer these discussion questions thoroughly.  Provide re.docx
 
Please click on this link and follow the directions to complete the .docx
Please click on this link and follow the directions to complete the .docxPlease click on this link and follow the directions to complete the .docx
Please click on this link and follow the directions to complete the .docx
 
Please choose one of the following questions, and post your resp.docx
Please choose one of the following questions, and post your resp.docxPlease choose one of the following questions, and post your resp.docx
Please choose one of the following questions, and post your resp.docx
 
Please answer the questions in paragraphs containing at least fi.docx
Please answer the questions in paragraphs containing at least fi.docxPlease answer the questions in paragraphs containing at least fi.docx
Please answer the questions in paragraphs containing at least fi.docx
 
Please answer the following three questions in one to two paragraphs.docx
Please answer the following three questions in one to two paragraphs.docxPlease answer the following three questions in one to two paragraphs.docx
Please answer the following three questions in one to two paragraphs.docx
 
Please answer the following1.  Transformational leadership and .docx
Please answer the following1.  Transformational leadership and .docxPlease answer the following1.  Transformational leadership and .docx
Please answer the following1.  Transformational leadership and .docx
 
Please answer the below questionDescribe social bandwidth and s.docx
Please answer the below questionDescribe social bandwidth and s.docxPlease answer the below questionDescribe social bandwidth and s.docx
Please answer the below questionDescribe social bandwidth and s.docx
 
Please answer the following questions1.- Please name the fu.docx
Please answer the following questions1.- Please name the fu.docxPlease answer the following questions1.- Please name the fu.docx
Please answer the following questions1.- Please name the fu.docx
 
Please answer the following questions1.- Please name the follow.docx
Please answer the following questions1.- Please name the follow.docxPlease answer the following questions1.- Please name the follow.docx
Please answer the following questions1.- Please name the follow.docx
 
Please answer the following questions with supporting examples and f.docx
Please answer the following questions with supporting examples and f.docxPlease answer the following questions with supporting examples and f.docx
Please answer the following questions with supporting examples and f.docx
 
Please answer the following questions about air and water pollution .docx
Please answer the following questions about air and water pollution .docxPlease answer the following questions about air and water pollution .docx
Please answer the following questions about air and water pollution .docx
 
please answer the following 7 questions in its entirety.  #11.C.docx
please answer the following 7 questions in its entirety.  #11.C.docxplease answer the following 7 questions in its entirety.  #11.C.docx
please answer the following 7 questions in its entirety.  #11.C.docx
 
Please answer the questions listed below and submit in a word docume.docx
Please answer the questions listed below and submit in a word docume.docxPlease answer the questions listed below and submit in a word docume.docx
Please answer the questions listed below and submit in a word docume.docx
 

Recently uploaded

MICROBIOLOGY biochemical test detailed.pptx
MICROBIOLOGY biochemical test detailed.pptxMICROBIOLOGY biochemical test detailed.pptx
MICROBIOLOGY biochemical test detailed.pptxabhijeetpadhi001
 
Organic Name Reactions for the students and aspirants of Chemistry12th.pptx
Organic Name Reactions  for the students and aspirants of Chemistry12th.pptxOrganic Name Reactions  for the students and aspirants of Chemistry12th.pptx
Organic Name Reactions for the students and aspirants of Chemistry12th.pptxVS Mahajan Coaching Centre
 
POINT- BIOCHEMISTRY SEM 2 ENZYMES UNIT 5.pptx
POINT- BIOCHEMISTRY SEM 2 ENZYMES UNIT 5.pptxPOINT- BIOCHEMISTRY SEM 2 ENZYMES UNIT 5.pptx
POINT- BIOCHEMISTRY SEM 2 ENZYMES UNIT 5.pptxSayali Powar
 
Procuring digital preservation CAN be quick and painless with our new dynamic...
Procuring digital preservation CAN be quick and painless with our new dynamic...Procuring digital preservation CAN be quick and painless with our new dynamic...
Procuring digital preservation CAN be quick and painless with our new dynamic...Jisc
 
Framing an Appropriate Research Question 6b9b26d93da94caf993c038d9efcdedb.pdf
Framing an Appropriate Research Question 6b9b26d93da94caf993c038d9efcdedb.pdfFraming an Appropriate Research Question 6b9b26d93da94caf993c038d9efcdedb.pdf
Framing an Appropriate Research Question 6b9b26d93da94caf993c038d9efcdedb.pdfUjwalaBharambe
 
Introduction to AI in Higher Education_draft.pptx
Introduction to AI in Higher Education_draft.pptxIntroduction to AI in Higher Education_draft.pptx
Introduction to AI in Higher Education_draft.pptxpboyjonauth
 
Historical philosophical, theoretical, and legal foundations of special and i...
Historical philosophical, theoretical, and legal foundations of special and i...Historical philosophical, theoretical, and legal foundations of special and i...
Historical philosophical, theoretical, and legal foundations of special and i...jaredbarbolino94
 
“Oh GOSH! Reflecting on Hackteria's Collaborative Practices in a Global Do-It...
“Oh GOSH! Reflecting on Hackteria's Collaborative Practices in a Global Do-It...“Oh GOSH! Reflecting on Hackteria's Collaborative Practices in a Global Do-It...
“Oh GOSH! Reflecting on Hackteria's Collaborative Practices in a Global Do-It...Marc Dusseiller Dusjagr
 
18-04-UA_REPORT_MEDIALITERAСY_INDEX-DM_23-1-final-eng.pdf
18-04-UA_REPORT_MEDIALITERAСY_INDEX-DM_23-1-final-eng.pdf18-04-UA_REPORT_MEDIALITERAСY_INDEX-DM_23-1-final-eng.pdf
18-04-UA_REPORT_MEDIALITERAСY_INDEX-DM_23-1-final-eng.pdfssuser54595a
 
Capitol Tech U Doctoral Presentation - April 2024.pptx
Capitol Tech U Doctoral Presentation - April 2024.pptxCapitol Tech U Doctoral Presentation - April 2024.pptx
Capitol Tech U Doctoral Presentation - April 2024.pptxCapitolTechU
 
Earth Day Presentation wow hello nice great
Earth Day Presentation wow hello nice greatEarth Day Presentation wow hello nice great
Earth Day Presentation wow hello nice greatYousafMalik24
 
Difference Between Search & Browse Methods in Odoo 17
Difference Between Search & Browse Methods in Odoo 17Difference Between Search & Browse Methods in Odoo 17
Difference Between Search & Browse Methods in Odoo 17Celine George
 
Solving Puzzles Benefits Everyone (English).pptx
Solving Puzzles Benefits Everyone (English).pptxSolving Puzzles Benefits Everyone (English).pptx
Solving Puzzles Benefits Everyone (English).pptxOH TEIK BIN
 
How to Configure Email Server in Odoo 17
How to Configure Email Server in Odoo 17How to Configure Email Server in Odoo 17
How to Configure Email Server in Odoo 17Celine George
 
MARGINALIZATION (Different learners in Marginalized Group
MARGINALIZATION (Different learners in Marginalized GroupMARGINALIZATION (Different learners in Marginalized Group
MARGINALIZATION (Different learners in Marginalized GroupJonathanParaisoCruz
 
DATA STRUCTURE AND ALGORITHM for beginners
DATA STRUCTURE AND ALGORITHM for beginnersDATA STRUCTURE AND ALGORITHM for beginners
DATA STRUCTURE AND ALGORITHM for beginnersSabitha Banu
 
Types of Journalistic Writing Grade 8.pptx
Types of Journalistic Writing Grade 8.pptxTypes of Journalistic Writing Grade 8.pptx
Types of Journalistic Writing Grade 8.pptxEyham Joco
 
ENGLISH 7_Q4_LESSON 2_ Employing a Variety of Strategies for Effective Interp...
ENGLISH 7_Q4_LESSON 2_ Employing a Variety of Strategies for Effective Interp...ENGLISH 7_Q4_LESSON 2_ Employing a Variety of Strategies for Effective Interp...
ENGLISH 7_Q4_LESSON 2_ Employing a Variety of Strategies for Effective Interp...JhezDiaz1
 

Recently uploaded (20)

MICROBIOLOGY biochemical test detailed.pptx
MICROBIOLOGY biochemical test detailed.pptxMICROBIOLOGY biochemical test detailed.pptx
MICROBIOLOGY biochemical test detailed.pptx
 
Organic Name Reactions for the students and aspirants of Chemistry12th.pptx
Organic Name Reactions  for the students and aspirants of Chemistry12th.pptxOrganic Name Reactions  for the students and aspirants of Chemistry12th.pptx
Organic Name Reactions for the students and aspirants of Chemistry12th.pptx
 
TataKelola dan KamSiber Kecerdasan Buatan v022.pdf
TataKelola dan KamSiber Kecerdasan Buatan v022.pdfTataKelola dan KamSiber Kecerdasan Buatan v022.pdf
TataKelola dan KamSiber Kecerdasan Buatan v022.pdf
 
POINT- BIOCHEMISTRY SEM 2 ENZYMES UNIT 5.pptx
POINT- BIOCHEMISTRY SEM 2 ENZYMES UNIT 5.pptxPOINT- BIOCHEMISTRY SEM 2 ENZYMES UNIT 5.pptx
POINT- BIOCHEMISTRY SEM 2 ENZYMES UNIT 5.pptx
 
Procuring digital preservation CAN be quick and painless with our new dynamic...
Procuring digital preservation CAN be quick and painless with our new dynamic...Procuring digital preservation CAN be quick and painless with our new dynamic...
Procuring digital preservation CAN be quick and painless with our new dynamic...
 
Framing an Appropriate Research Question 6b9b26d93da94caf993c038d9efcdedb.pdf
Framing an Appropriate Research Question 6b9b26d93da94caf993c038d9efcdedb.pdfFraming an Appropriate Research Question 6b9b26d93da94caf993c038d9efcdedb.pdf
Framing an Appropriate Research Question 6b9b26d93da94caf993c038d9efcdedb.pdf
 
Introduction to AI in Higher Education_draft.pptx
Introduction to AI in Higher Education_draft.pptxIntroduction to AI in Higher Education_draft.pptx
Introduction to AI in Higher Education_draft.pptx
 
Historical philosophical, theoretical, and legal foundations of special and i...
Historical philosophical, theoretical, and legal foundations of special and i...Historical philosophical, theoretical, and legal foundations of special and i...
Historical philosophical, theoretical, and legal foundations of special and i...
 
“Oh GOSH! Reflecting on Hackteria's Collaborative Practices in a Global Do-It...
“Oh GOSH! Reflecting on Hackteria's Collaborative Practices in a Global Do-It...“Oh GOSH! Reflecting on Hackteria's Collaborative Practices in a Global Do-It...
“Oh GOSH! Reflecting on Hackteria's Collaborative Practices in a Global Do-It...
 
18-04-UA_REPORT_MEDIALITERAСY_INDEX-DM_23-1-final-eng.pdf
18-04-UA_REPORT_MEDIALITERAСY_INDEX-DM_23-1-final-eng.pdf18-04-UA_REPORT_MEDIALITERAСY_INDEX-DM_23-1-final-eng.pdf
18-04-UA_REPORT_MEDIALITERAСY_INDEX-DM_23-1-final-eng.pdf
 
Capitol Tech U Doctoral Presentation - April 2024.pptx
Capitol Tech U Doctoral Presentation - April 2024.pptxCapitol Tech U Doctoral Presentation - April 2024.pptx
Capitol Tech U Doctoral Presentation - April 2024.pptx
 
Earth Day Presentation wow hello nice great
Earth Day Presentation wow hello nice greatEarth Day Presentation wow hello nice great
Earth Day Presentation wow hello nice great
 
Difference Between Search & Browse Methods in Odoo 17
Difference Between Search & Browse Methods in Odoo 17Difference Between Search & Browse Methods in Odoo 17
Difference Between Search & Browse Methods in Odoo 17
 
Solving Puzzles Benefits Everyone (English).pptx
Solving Puzzles Benefits Everyone (English).pptxSolving Puzzles Benefits Everyone (English).pptx
Solving Puzzles Benefits Everyone (English).pptx
 
How to Configure Email Server in Odoo 17
How to Configure Email Server in Odoo 17How to Configure Email Server in Odoo 17
How to Configure Email Server in Odoo 17
 
ESSENTIAL of (CS/IT/IS) class 06 (database)
ESSENTIAL of (CS/IT/IS) class 06 (database)ESSENTIAL of (CS/IT/IS) class 06 (database)
ESSENTIAL of (CS/IT/IS) class 06 (database)
 
MARGINALIZATION (Different learners in Marginalized Group
MARGINALIZATION (Different learners in Marginalized GroupMARGINALIZATION (Different learners in Marginalized Group
MARGINALIZATION (Different learners in Marginalized Group
 
DATA STRUCTURE AND ALGORITHM for beginners
DATA STRUCTURE AND ALGORITHM for beginnersDATA STRUCTURE AND ALGORITHM for beginners
DATA STRUCTURE AND ALGORITHM for beginners
 
Types of Journalistic Writing Grade 8.pptx
Types of Journalistic Writing Grade 8.pptxTypes of Journalistic Writing Grade 8.pptx
Types of Journalistic Writing Grade 8.pptx
 
ENGLISH 7_Q4_LESSON 2_ Employing a Variety of Strategies for Effective Interp...
ENGLISH 7_Q4_LESSON 2_ Employing a Variety of Strategies for Effective Interp...ENGLISH 7_Q4_LESSON 2_ Employing a Variety of Strategies for Effective Interp...
ENGLISH 7_Q4_LESSON 2_ Employing a Variety of Strategies for Effective Interp...
 

Macroeconomics NameCourseInstructorInstitutio.docx

  • 1. Macroeconomics Name: Course: Instructor: Institution: Date of Submission The Key Issues Addressed in the Paper How the Federal Reserve System and the Treasury Relate; The Pre-Crisis Cash Management; Cash Management by Treasury Following the Onset of the Crisis; and The Treatment of the Financial Crisis. How the Federal Reserve System and the Treasury Relate The U.S. Treasury channels a good part of its receipts the TGA; It disburses the payments made into the same account; This ensures a continuous fund flows from the depository institutions to TGA and back again; The interface required joint management between Treasury and Fed during the crisis
  • 2. How the Federal Reserve System and the Treasury Relate There are a number of ways in which the roles of the Treasury and the Fed relate even though they may seem sufficiently distinct. The U.S. Treasury channels a good part of its receipts the TGA (Adrian, 2009). Similarly, it disburses the payments made into the same account. This ensures that there is always continuity in fund flows from the depository institutions to this account and back again. This continuous flow of funds between the account and the deposit-taking financial institutions played a crucial during the Financial Crisis of 2008-09 since the TGA is maintained in the Fed’s books. The upsurge in the TGA balancing arising from the Treasury’s net receipts reserves drained from the banking system. Also, in the case where there is an absence of offsetting actions, this would put pressure on the interest rate of federal funds (Adrian, 2009). On the other hand, declines in TGA balances as a result of Treasury net expenditures boosted reserves to the entire banking system with the consequence that the is a downward pressure on the federal funds rate stemming from the absence of offsetting actions. The result of this dynamic is an important interface between the Fed operations and the Treasury. This interface required joint management during the crisis and the next section shows how the Fed and the Treasury jointly managed the interface from the onset of the financial crisis (Santoro, 2012). 3 The Pre-Crisis Cash Management The pre-crisis cash management aimed at volatility dampening of the cash reserves; To suppress the volatility, the Fed carried out large scale open market operations (OMO) more frequently; The key objectives were: Tax collection; Stabilizing the TGA balance; and Generate interest income for the treasury
  • 3. The Pre-Crisis Cash Management The cash management prior to the crisis was aimed at volatility dampening of the cash reserves. This would have been worse if the Treasury had all the revenues as they came in into the TGA and if it had held them there up to the time of disbursement. To suppress the volatility, the Federal Reserve System would have been forced to carry out large scale open market operations (OMO) more frequently. The focus would have been to drain reserves in the instances when TGA balances were diminishing and increasing reserves when the balances were swelling (Santoro, 2012). The Treasury sought to maintain a stable balance in TGA and this worked more efficiently in its Tax and Loan program. Before the onset of the crisis the three objectives of cash management by the treasury under the Tax and Loan program were to collect federal tax receipts, stabilize the TGA balance, and to generate (for the Treasury) interest income (Adrian, 2009). To achieve its tax collection objective, a private deposit-taking institution could take part in Tax and Loan program by being a collector institution, a retainer institution, or an investor institution. As a collector institution, a depository institution would act as a tax collection conduit to accept tax payments from corporations and other businesses (basically personal income withholding taxes, social security contributions, and corporate taxes) (Santoro, 2012). They would then transfer the collection to the TGA. As a retainer institution the depository institutions would still accept the but this would be pegged on the limit set by the institution and also pledge collateral and retain the payments in some interest-bearing account up to such a time that the Treasury would call for them. Any excess of the Main Account above the set limit would be transferred to the TGA. As an investor institution, the depository institution accepted (from Treasury) direct investments and credited them
  • 4. to the Main Account upon being collateralized (Santoro, 2012). 4 Cash Management by Treasury Following the Onset of the Crisis Treasury responded by selling Treasury bills through its Supplementary Financing Program (SFP); The was to drain (mop out) excess reserves in the banking system; SFP comprised a series of T-bills whose proceeds were deposited at Fed’s newly created SFP A/c; Fed’s announcement of beginning to pay interest on the reserves further led to mop-out. Cash Management by Treasury Following the Onset of the Crisis When the crisis began in 2008, the Treasury made the first response by selling Treasury bills through its Supplementary Financing Program (SFP). The consequence of this intervention was that the reserves were drained from the banking and cut down the excess reserve volumes. The SFP comprised a series of T-bills, save for the Treasury’s current borrowing account, whose purpose was to provide cash to be used for lending and liquidity initiatives at the Fed. The proceeds for the SFP sales were deposited at the Fed in the newly created Supplementary Financing Program account. This initiative succeeded in draining about $100 billion from the banking system (Adrian, 2009). Fed announced that it would start paying interest on the reserve balances. This was aimed at allowing Fed to go on with the lending program so as to address the credit market conditions and to keep maintaining the funds rate as the target level, with or without the SFP. The program resulted into stability up to the
  • 5. end of the crisis in September 2009 when Treasury embarked on the redemption of maturing bills. This was done in expectancy of a debt ceiling constraint. 5 The Treatment of the Financial Crisis Fed and Treasury applied cash management policies to contain the crisis; Policies aimed at cash reserve volatility dampening and price stability; OMO enabled Fed to mop out excess reserves during crisis; This further helped to maintain a stable TGA balance The Treatment of the Financial Crisis The treatment of the financial crisis by the Treasury and the Fed prior and even after can be said to be commendable. Stability of prices in the economy is a core monetary policy objective and thus was done prior to the onset of the crisis. The Fed and Treasury pursued cash management policies that targeted volatility dampening of the cash reserves (Domar, 2006). If the cash reserves are allowed to oscillate with wide amplitudes then this can subject the economy to varied levels of money supply. The effect of this would be that the prices would vary quite widely within a short period of time and thus bringing instability even into the goods prices (Mankiw, 2014). Applying the monetary policy tools such as OMO to control the supply of currency was in order. The focus would have been to drain reserves in the instances when TGA balances were diminishing and increasing reserves when the balances were swelling. The Treasury sought to maintain a stable balance in TGA and this worked more efficiently in its Tax and Loan program (Mankiw, 2014). This was triggered by the three objectives at the time that included a continuous tax receipt flows, stabilization of TGA, and generation of interest income
  • 6. for the Treasury (Mankiw, 2014). At the onset of the financial crisis in 2008, the immediate objective was to drain excess reserve volumes in the banking system. The Treasury came up with the SFP which worked effectively through its T-bills. The effect was that the cash to be used for lending and liquidity initiatives at the Fed was provided. Effectively, through the SFP about $100 billion was drained from the banking system thus bringing stability (Branson, Macroeconomic Theory and practice, 2006). The announcement by Fed that it would start paying interest on the reserve balances with an aim of allowing Fed to go on with the lending program so as to address the credit market conditions and to keep maintaining the funds rate as the target level, with or without the SFP was very productive. It resulted into stability up to the end of the crisis in September 2009 when Treasury embarked on the redemption of maturing bills. This intervention was consistent with argument in Mankiw (2014). 6 An Outline the Author’s Arguments Two approaches key to author's argument Cash Management: SFP was a management strategy to drain excess reserves alongside T-bill sales; Investment Strategy: announcement of increases in interest payments caused investors to reduce their liquidity holdings thus further draining excess reserves An Outline the Author’s Arguments The author points, basically, at two approaches that worked best for the Fed in collaboration with the U.S. Treasury in managing the financial crisis of 2008-09. These are close working relationship between the Fed and the Treasury in cash management, and the second one is the manipulation of investment strategy through compelling T-bill purchase or sales
  • 7. through raising interest rates. The SFP was a cash management tool meant to drain reserves from the banking system so as to reduce overall liquidity in the economy. This worked effectively to mop up the excess reserves. By reducing the reserves in the banking system, the banks were left with fewer funds to give to the people and this worked to contain the crisis by reducing excess flow of funds. OMO was the second cash management tool that Santoro (2012) points out. By selling T-bills to the public and the depository instituions, the Fed managed to mop out excess liquidity in the banking system and this helped it in the cash manageemnt. The second idea fronted Santoro (2012) was that of investment stratgies. The idea was to announce increases and decreases in the T-bills rates and retirng of debts. When the Treasury announced increases in the T-bill rates, the banks and individual investors purchased more of the T-bills thus reducing the excess reserves form the banking system. A decrease in the intersest rates would trigger low demand for the same. 7 References Adrian, T. C. (2009). The Federal Reserve’s Primary Dealer Credit Facility: Federal Reserve Bank of New York. Current Issues in Economics and Finance 15, no. 4 . Domar, H. (2006). Macroeconomic Theory and Policy. New York: sage. Mankiw, G. N. (2014). Principles of Economics 7th Edition. South-Western College Pub. Santoro, P. J. (2012). The Evolution of Treasury Cash Management during the Financial Crisis. current issues in Economics and Finance Volume 18, Number , 1-11.
  • 12. en t_ is su es The Evolution of Treasury Cash Management during the Financial Crisis Paul J. Santoro The U.S. Treasury and the Federal Reserve System have long enjoyed a close relationship, each helping the other to carry out certain statutory responsibilities. This relationship proved benefi cial during the 2008-09 fi nancial crisis, when the Treasury altered its cash management practices to facilitate the Fed’s dramatic expansion of credit to banks, primary dealers, and foreign central banks. L ike most households and businesses, the U.S. Treasury maintains a cash balance to buffer short-run fl uctuations in receipts and disbursements. Unlike most households, however, the Treasury’s cash balance is highly volatile: between January 1, 2006, and December 31, 2010, it varied from as little as $3.1 billion to as much as $188.6 billion (Chart 1).1 The Treasury divides its cash balance between two types of accounts: a Treasury General Account (TGA) at the Federal Reserve and
  • 13. Treasury Tax and Loan Note accounts (TT&L accounts) at private depository institutions.2 The behavior of the respective account balances changed dramatically in the fall of 2008. As shown in Chart 2, prior to the fi nancial crisis that followed the collapse of Lehman Brothers on September 15, 2008 (hereafter, “the crisis”), the TGA mostly fl uctuated in a narrow band around $5 billion while TT&L balances varied more widely.3 In contrast, since the fall of 2008, TT&L balances have fl uctuated in a narrow band around $2 billion and the TGA has varied widely. 1 We defi ne the Treasury’s cash balance as the difference between the Total Operating Balance and the Supplementary Financing Program Account as shown on the Daily Treasury Statement. 2 The Federal Reserve maintains the TGA as part of its statutory obligation to serve as fi scal agent of the United States (Manypenny and Bermudez 1992). The TGA has existed since January 1916 (1916 Treasury Annual Report, p. 6); TT&L accounts, originally named “Liberty Loan deposit accounts,” have existed since May 1917 (Treasury Circular no. 79, May 16, 1917, reprinted in 1917 Treasury Annual Report, p. 131; Treasury Circular no. 81, May 29, 1917, reprinted in 1917 Treasury Annual Report, p. 124). 3 While the start date of the fi nancial crisis is debatable and may have been as early as 2007, the effect of the crisis on Treasury cash management coincided with the rapid expansion of the Federal Reserve’s balance sheet after the collapse of Lehman Brothers
  • 14. in September 2008. 2 CURRENT ISSUES IN ECONOMICS AND FINANCE ❖ Volume 18 Number 3 This edition of Current Issues, one of a group of articles describing Federal Reserve responses to the crisis,4 explains how a change in Federal Reserve credit policy during the crisis was associated with the change in Treasury cash manage- 4 See also Armantier, Krieger, and McAndrews (2008), Adrian, Burke, and McAndrews (2009), Fleming, Hrung, and Keane (2009), Garbade, Keane, Logan, Stokes, and Wolgemuth (2010), Adrian, Kimbrough, and Marchioni (2011), Gagnon, Raskin, Remache, and Sack (2011), and Goldberg, Kennedy, and Miu (2011). ment practices shown in Chart 2. Understanding the relation- ship between Federal Reserve credit policy and Treasury cash management is important because the relationship illuminates an important but sometimes unappreciated interface between the Treasury and the Fed. It also underscores the symbiotic relation- ship between the two institutions, in which each assists the other in fulfi lling its statutory responsibilities. Subsequent sections of this article will detail the changes in Federal Reserve operating procedures and Treasury cash
  • 15. Sources: U.S. Department of the Treasury, Daily Treasury Statement; authors’ calculations. Note: Cash balances are computed as the difference between the Total Operating Balance and the Supplementary Financing Program Account as shown on the Daily Treasury Statement. Billions of dollars 2006 2010 Chart 1 Treasury Cash Balances 2007 2008 2009 200 160 120 80 40 0 Source: U.S. Department of the Treasury, Daily Treasury Statement. Billions of dollars
  • 16. 2006 2010 Chart 2 Balances in the Treasury General Account and Treasury Tax and Loan Note Accounts 2007 2008 2009 200 160 120 80 40 Treasury General Account Treasury Tax and Loan Note accounts 0 management during the crisis. The fi rst section, however, presents a framework for the analysis by reviewing the core missions of the Treasury and the Federal Reserve and explaining how each institution seeks to fulfi ll its mandate. The Missions of the U.S. Treasury and the Federal Reserve The Treasury
  • 17. A principal mission of the U.S. Treasury is collecting income taxes and other taxes prescribed by statute and funding the fi nancial commitments of the U.S. government.5 In the course of fulfi lling this mandate, the Treasury undertakes a variety of debt management operations, including refi nancing maturing debt with new issues, selling additional debt when expenditures exceed revenues, and retiring debt when the reverse is true. As noted earlier, the Treasury maintains accounts at the Federal Reserve and at private depository institutions to buffer day-to- day fl uctuations in cash fl ows that cannot be accommodated effi ciently with debt management operations. The Federal Reserve A principal mission of the Federal Reserve System is managing the U.S. money supply and credit market conditions to promote maximum employment with stable prices and moderate long- term interest rates.6 Prior to the fall of 2008, the Fed sought to carry out this mandate primarily by (1) targeting the interest rate on overnight loans in the federal funds market and (2) managing the supply of reserves available to the banking system to stabilize the federal funds rate at the target rate. Offi cials purchased (sold) Treasury securities, either outright or through repurchase agreements,7 when they wanted to add (drain) reserves to keep the funds rate from rising above (falling below) the target. In the course of responding to the crisis, the Fed provided unprecedented quantities of central bank credit to banks, primary dealers, foreign central banks, and others. The increase in assets on the Fed’s balance sheet generated a corresponding increase in central bank liabilities. Currency in circulation expanded modestly, from $835 billion on September 10, 2008, to $890 billion at the end of the year, but deposits at the central bank ballooned from $38 billion to $1.2 trillion,8 far beyond
  • 18. what depository institutions were required to hold. As described below, the Fed and the Treasury adopted a variety of novel procedures 5 See “Duties and Functions of the U.S. Department of the Treasury,” available at www.treasury.gov/about/role-of-treasury/Pages/default.aspx. 6 See Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System (2005, p. 1). 7 A repurchase agreement is a sale of securities coupled with an agreement to repurchase the same securities at a specifi ed price on a later date. Repurchase agreements are also called “repos.” 8 Deposits at the central bank include reserve balances of depository institutions, U.S. Treasury deposits, foreign offi cial deposits, and service- related deposits (including required clearing balances and adjustments to compensate for fl oat). to prevent the expanding quantity of reserves from driving the federal funds rate to zero. The Interface between the Federal Reserve and the Treasury At fi rst impression, the Federal Reserve and Treasury mandates might seem suffi ciently distinct that the two institutions should be able to function independently of each other. However, the Treasury funnels most of its receipts into, and it disburses most of its payments from, the TGA. Thus, there is a continuous fl ow of funds from private depository institutions to the TGA and back again. During fi scal year 2010, $11.6 trillion fl owed into, and then out of, the TGA.
  • 19. Flows of funds between the TGA and private depository institutions were important prior to the crisis because the TGA is maintained on the books of the Federal Reserve; increases in TGA balances stemming from Treasury net receipts drained reserves from the banking system and, in the absence of offset- ting actions, put upward pressure on the federal funds rate. Conversely, decreases in TGA balances resulting from Treasury net expenditures added reserves to the banking system and, absent offsetting actions, put downward pressure on the funds rate. This dynamic created an important interface between Treasury and Federal Reserve operations. The sections that follow describe fi rst how Treasury and Federal Reserve offi cials cooperated to manage the interface before the crisis, and then how the interface has changed since the onset of the crisis and the expansion of the Fed’s balance sheet. Treasury Cash Management before the Crisis If, in the pre-crisis regime, the Treasury had deposited all of its receipts in the TGA as soon as they came in, and if it had held the funds in the TGA until they were disbursed, the supply of reserves available to the banking system—and hence the overnight federal funds rate—would have exhibited undesir- able volatility. To dampen the volatility, the Fed would have had to conduct frequent and large-scale open market operations, draining reserves when TGA balances were declining and add- ing reserves when TGA balances were rising.9 A more effi cient strategy, and the one used by the Treasury in its Tax and Loan program, was to seek to maintain a stable TGA balance. The Treasury Tax and Loan Program Prior to the onset of the crisis, the Treasury Tax and Loan program had three principal objectives: processing federal tax
  • 20. 9 This actually happened between 1974 and 1978. During this period, the TGA experienced large fl uctuations when the Treasury sought to limit aggregate TT&L balances to about $1.5 billion (Lovett 1978, p. 43), and the Federal Reserve was obliged to conduct correspondingly large and frequent open market operations (Brockschmidt 1975; McDonough 1976). The need for aggressive intervention ended in 1978 following a major reorganization of the TT&L program (Lovett 1978; Lang 1979). www.newyorkfed.org/research/cur rent_issues 3 4 CURRENT ISSUES IN ECONOMICS AND FINANCE ❖ Volume 18 Number 3 receipts, stabilizing the TGA balance, and generating interest income for the Treasury.10 Collecting Federal Tax Receipts A private depository institution could participate in the TT&L program in any of three ways: as a collector institution, as a retainer institution, or as an investor institution. A collector institution was a tax collection conduit. It accepted tax payments from businesses (primarily withholdings of per- sonal income taxes, corporate income taxes, and social security contributions) in electronic form and at its teller windows and transferred the payments to the TGA.
  • 21. A retainer institution also accepted tax payments but, subject to a limit specifi ed by the institution and pledge of suffi cient collateral, retained the payments in an interest-bearing “Main Account” until called for by the Treasury. If a Main Account balance exceeded the institution’s limit, or if it exceeded the collateral value of the assets pledged by the institution, the excess was transferred promptly to the TGA. An investor institution did everything a retainer institution did and, as described below, also accepted direct investments from the Treasury.11 The investments were credited to the institution’s Main Account and had to be collateralized. Stabilizing the TGA Balance Before the onset of the crisis, the Treasury typically aimed to maintain a $5 billion balance in the TGA.12 The Treasury used well-timed cash calls13 and direct investments to maintain the actual balance close to the target most of the time (see Chart 2). Each morning Treasury cash managers and analysts at the Federal Reserve Bank of New York estimated the current day’s receipts and disbursements. During a telephone conference call at 9 a.m., they combined the estimates with the previous day’s closing TGA balance, scheduled payments of principal and interest, scheduled proceeds from sales of new securities, and other similar items to produce an estimate of the current day’s closing balance. If the estimated closing balance exceeded the target, the Treasury would invest the excess at investor institutions 10 Garbade, Partlan, and Santoro (2004) describe in more detail the Treasury Tax and Loan program as it operated before the crisis. The Treasury is presently in
  • 22. the midst of a major revamping of its cash management systems. See Financial Management Service, “Collections and Cash Management Modernization (CCMM),” available at www.fms.treas.gov/ccmm/index.html. 11 A direct investment was a Treasury-directed transfer of funds from the TGA to Treasury’s TT&L accounts at investor banks. 12 The target balance, established in 1988, had to be large enough to provide a high degree of confi dence that the TGA would not be overdrawn at the end of a business day since the Fed was not authorized to lend directly to the Treasury. The target balance was sometimes bumped up to $7 billion when cash fl ows were unusually heavy, such as the intervals around tax payment dates. 13 Cash calls are Treasury-directed transfers from TT&L accounts to the TGA. that had suffi cient free collateral and room under their balance limits to accept additional funds.14 If the estimated balance was below target, the Treasury would call for funds from retainer and investor institutions to make up the shortfall. Earning Interest on TT&L Balances The Treasury had three ways to earn interest on TT&L balances. Conventional Main Account balances earned interest at the federal funds rate less 25 basis points. In addition, the Treasury could, at its discretion, make overnight investments in repur- chase agreements (repos) and term investments through its Term Investment Option (TIO) program. The relationship between the rate on Main Account balances
  • 23. and the federal funds rate was set in 1978, in the course of a major overhaul of the TT&L program. A market-linked rate equal to the funds rate less 25 basis points was deemed appropriate for collateralized TT&L balances because, at the time, it was approximately equal to the rate on overnight repurchase agree- ments on Treasury collateral. However, by the late 1990s, the spread between the federal funds rate and the repo rate had narrowed to 5 basis points and the Treasury began to consider alternatives to obtain a higher rate of return on investments. The fi rst alternative, the TIO program, was introduced on an experimental basis in April 2002 and made permanent in November 2003.15 A TIO auction was similar to a Treasury bill auction, but in reverse. The Treasury offered to invest (rather than borrow) a specifi ed amount of money for a specifi ed term and participating institutions bid on the money. On average from March 2006 to March 2007, institutions were willing to pay about 18 basis points more for TIO balances than they had to pay on Main Account balances,16 in part because TIO balances would remain with the institution for a specifi ed term rather than being subject to daily calls. In March 2006, the Treasury initiated a pilot program of investing excess funds through overnight repurchase agreements. During the pilot program, the Treasury invested an average of $2.7 billion per day in repurchase agreements against Treasury collateral. Daily offerings ranged between $500 million and $6 billion.17 On average from March 2006 to March 2007, 14 Occasionally, net fl ows into the TGA were so large that the Treasury exhausted the capacity of investor institutions to accept additional funds
  • 24. and TGA balances rose above the target level by more than several billion dollars. For more on stabilizing the TGA and the timing of direct investments and calls, see, for example, the discussion of the April 2000 tax payments in Garbade, Partlan, and Santoro (2004, p. 6). 15 See, Garbade, Partlan, and Santoro (2004) and Hrung (2007). 16 Government Accountability Offi ce (2007, p. 13, Table 2). 17 U.S. Department of the Treasury, Financial Management Service, “Repurchase Agreement (Repo) Program,” available at http://www.fms.treas.gov/tip/repo/ index.html. www.newyorkfed.org/research/cur rent_issues 5 institutions were willing to pay about 21 basis points more for repo balances than they had to pay on Main Account balances,18 in part for the enhanced certainty of obtaining and retaining funds until the next business day. Chart 3 shows how TT&L balances were divided among conventional Main Account balances, TIO investments, and repo investments prior to the crisis. Treasury Cash Management following the Onset of the Crisis: The Initial Structure It quickly became clear during the week of September 15, 2008, that the United States was heading into a major fi nancial crisis. On Tuesday, September 16, a $63 billion money market mutual fund “broke the buck” and turned what had been a slow leakage
  • 25. of shareholder balances into a full-scale run.19 Later the same day, the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, acting “with the full support of the Treasury Department,” authorized the Federal Reserve Bank of New York to lend up to $85 billion to American International Group, Inc. (AIG).20 18 Government Accountability Offi ce (2007, p. 13, Table 2). 19 Investment Company Institute (2009). A money market mutual fund is said to break the buck when its net asset value falls below $0.995 per share. In that case, the fund has to begin to redeem its shares at net asset value or otherwise act to ensure fair treatment of its shareholders. 20 Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, press release, September 16, 2008; U.S. Department of the Treasury, “Statement by Secretary Henry M. Paulson, Jr., on Federal Reserve Actions surrounding AIG,” press release, September 16, 2008. By the close of business on Wednesday, September 17, AIG had borrowed $28 billion, primary dealers had borrowed $60 billion (through the Primary Dealer Credit Facility21), and depository institutions had added $10 billion to their discount window borrowings. In all, Federal Reserve credit expanded by $100 billion in just two days, and there was more to come.22 As a result of the Fed’s mushrooming loan portfolio, reserve balances of depository institutions increased from $25 billion on September 10 to $82 billion on September 17. It was clear that, in the absence of profound institutional change, reserve balances were going to be vastly in excess of requirements for the
  • 26. foresee- able future and federal funds were going to trade well below the target rate of 2 percent.23 21 Adrian, Burke, and McAndrews (2009) explain the origins and operation of the Primary Dealer Credit Facility. 22 On September 18, the Board of Governors announced that it had agreed to expand its swap lines with foreign central banks by $180 billion (Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, press release, September 18, 2008). Several counterparties promptly expanded their draws of U.S. dollars by $64 billion (Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, press release, December 1, 2010). On September 19, the Board announced the formation of the Asset-Backed Commercial Paper Money Market Mutual Fund Liquidity Facility (Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, press release, September 19, 2008). The facility opened for business on Monday, September 22, and within three days lent $73 billion. 23 The Federal Reserve Bank of New York’s annual report of domestic open market operations in 2008, prepared by the Bank’s Markets Group, notes that “after September 15, [2008], the magnitude of liquidity added to the system through various programs exceeded the Federal Reserve’s ability to offset with draining operations” (Federal Reserve Bank of New York 2009, p. 6).
  • 27. Sources: U.S. Department of the Treasury, Daily Treasury Statement; authors’ calculations. Billions of dollars 2006 2007 2008 Chart 3 Allocation of Treasury Tax and Loan Balances among Term Investment Option Balances, Coventional Main Account Balances, and Repurchase Agreements prior to September 15, 2008 0 30 60 90 120 150 Term Investment Option balances Conventional Main Account balances Repurchase agreements 6 CURRENT ISSUES IN ECONOMICS AND FINANCE ❖
  • 28. Volume 18 Number 3 The Supplementary Financing Program The fi rst Treasury cash management change following the onset of the crisis involved the sale of Treasury bills by the U.S. Treasury and the deposit of the proceeds with the Federal Reserve— actions that drained reserves from the banking system and reduced the volume of excess reserves. On Wednesday, September 17, the Treasury announced the initiation of “a temporary Supple- mentary Financing Program [SFP] at the request of the Federal Reserve.”24 The announcement stated that the program would “consist of a series of Treasury bills, apart from Treasury’s current borrowing program, which will provide cash for use in the Federal Reserve [lending and liquidity] initiatives.” 25 The Treasury announced three SFP sales that day for a total of $100 billion. The proceeds from the sales were deposited in a newly created SFP account at the Fed, thereby draining approxi- mately $100 billion of reserves from the banking system. By Friday, October 3, two weeks and two days after the start of the Supplementary Financing Program, the Treasury had issued eleven SFP bills (one of which was to refi nance a maturing SFP bill) and the program had drained about $355 billion of reserve balances. SFP bills peaked at $560 billion between October 20 and November 12 (Chart 4). On October 6, the Federal Reserve announced that it would begin to pay interest on reserve balances effective Thursday, October 9. This new feature of monetary policy was expected to allow the Fed to continue to use its lending program to address conditions in credit markets while also maintaining the funds rate close to the target level, even in the absence of the SFP
  • 29. program. 26 24 U.S. Department of the Treasury, “Treasury Announces Supplementary Financing Program,” press release, September 17, 2008. Emphasis added. 25 The novelty of the SFP program led to some confusion in describing the program. The New York Times, for example, reported the fi rst sale of SFP bills by stating, “In a sign of how short the Fed’s available reserves had become, the Treasury Department sold tens of billions of dollars of special ‘supplementary’ Treasury bills on September 17 to provide the Fed with extra cash” (“A New Role for the Fed: Investor of Last Resort,” New York Times, September 18, 2008, p. A1). In fact, the Federal Reserve can emit currency and create bank reserves at will and thus did not need any “extra cash.” What it could not fashion from its existing authorities was a way to drain massive quantities of reserves from the banking system. The Wall Street Journal got it right when it stated that the Treasury was “carrying out [a reserve] draining function in place of the Fed” (“U.S. Moves to Bolster Fed Balance Sheet – Treasury Auctions $40 Billion of Debt; More Sales on Tap,” Wall Street Journal, September 18, 2008, p. A3). 26 See Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, press release, October 6, 2008: “The payment of interest on excess reserves will permit the Federal Reserve to expand its balance sheet as necessary to provide the liquidity
  • 30. necessary to support fi nancial stability while implementing the monetary policy that is appropriate in light of the System’s macroeconomic objectives of maximum employment and price stability.” See also Federal Reserve Bank of New York (2009, p. 4): “In theory, the payment of interest on excess reserve balances allows the Federal Reserve to continue to use its lending programs to address conditions in the credit markets while also maintaining the fed funds rate close to the target established by the FOMC.” On November 17 the Treasury announced that it was trimming the size of the SFP program.27 By the end of 2008, there were $260 billion of SFP bills outstanding. The program stabilized at $200 billion in early March 2009 and remained at that level until late September 2009, when the Treasury began to redeem maturing bills for cash in anticipation of a debt ceiling constraint.28 The last SFP bill issued in the course of the original program was redeemed on December 29, 2009.29 The tenor—or term to maturity—of SFP bills issued in 2008 and 2009 ranged from just 7 days to as many as 101 days in the fi rst two months of the program, but stabilized at 70 days in 2009 when the overall size of the program fi rmed at $200 billion (Chart 5). Most SFP bills were issued to refi nance maturing SFP bills; in only two instances in 2009 was an SFP bill issued for new
  • 31. 27 U.S. Department of the Treasury, “Treasury Issues Debt Management Guidance on the Temporary Supplementary Financing Program,” press release, November 17, 2008. 28 See U.S. Department of the Treasury, “Treasury Issues Debt Management Guidance on the Supplementary Financing Program, press release, September 16, 2009; “U.S. Treasury to Scale Back Fed Program to Avoid Debt Ceiling,” Bloomberg .com, September 16, 2009; and “Treasury to Shrink Financing Program,” Wall Street Journal, September 16, 2009, p. A3. 29 On December 28, 2009, Congress raised the debt ceiling by $290 billion. Armed with enlarged issuance authority, the Treasury revived the Supplementary Financing Program. The revived program ran from the end of 2009 to mid-2011, when it was allowed to run down in the face of another debt ceiling constraint. For most of that time, the Treasury regularly and predictably auctioned $25 billion of eight-week SFP bills every week. Source: U.S. Department of the Treasury. Notes: SFP is Supplementary Financing Program. The first vertical dashed line in the chart marks the November 17, 2008, announcement by the Treasury that it would be reducing the size of the SFP program. The second vertical dashed line marks the September 16, 2009, announcement by the Treasury that it would begin to redeem,
  • 32. rather than refinance, maturing SFP bills. Chart 4 SFP Bills Outstanding Through December 29, 2009 0 100 200 300 400 500 600 Principal amount (billions of dollars) 2008 2009 www.newyorkfed.org/research/cur rent_issues 7 cash. The size of the SFP bills issued in 2008 and 2009 initially ranged from $30 billion to $60 billion, but stabilized at $30 billion to $35 billion in 2009 (Chart 6). Treasury Cash Management after the Fed Began Paying Interest on Reserves On October 6, 2008, when the Federal Reserve announced that
  • 33. it would begin to pay interest on reserves, it stated that it would pay the average target federal funds rate over a reserve main- tenance period, less 10 basis points, on required reserves and the lowest target rate over a maintenance period, less 75 basis points, on excess reserves.30 Following several changes in the target funds rate and the rate paid on required reserve balances and excess balances, the FOMC established (on December 16, 2008) a target range of zero to 25 basis points for the funds rate, and the Board of Governors announced a rate of 25 basis points on reserve balances.31 (The rate of interest on excess reserves is commonly known as the “IOER rate.”) Charts 7 and 8 show that the federal funds rate was persistently below the IOER rate from late 2008 through 2010. Consequences for Treasury Cash Management The structure of interest rates after December 2008 prompted the Treasury to make a second change in its cash management practices since it now had an economic incentive to keep its cash balances in the Treasury General Account rather than in Treasury Tax and Loan Note accounts. When the overnight federal funds rate fell below 25 basis points, the TT&L rate on Main Account balances went to zero and the likely rates of 30 Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, press release, October 6, 2008. 31 Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, press release, December 16, 2008. Source: U.S. Department of the Treasury. Note: SFP is Supplementary Financing Program.
  • 34. Chart 5 Tenor of SFP Bills Issued in 2008 and 2009 0 30 60 90 120 Number of days 2008 2009 Date of issue Source: U.S. Department of the Treasury. Note: SFP is Supplementary Financing Program. Chart 6 Size of SFP Bills Issued in 2008 and 2009 0 25 50 75 Principal amount (billions of SFP dollars)
  • 35. 2008 2009 Date of issue Sources: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System; Federal Reserve Bank of New York. Notes: IOER is the interest rate on excess reserves. Days marked on the horizontal axis denote the beginnings of reserve maintenance periods. Chart 7 Target Federal Funds Rate, IOER Rate, and Federal Funds Rate Percent 0 0.5 1.0 1.5 2.0 2.5 3.0 Au gu st
  • 36. 2 8 2008 Federal funds rate Target federal funds rate (or upper end of target range) IOER rate (when different from target federal funds rate) Se pt em be r 1 1 Se pt em be r 2 5 Oc to
  • 37. be r 9 Oc to be r 2 3 No ve m be r 6 No ve m be r 2 0 De ce m be r 4 De
  • 38. ce m be r 1 8 Ja nu ar y 1 2009 8 CURRENT ISSUES IN ECONOMICS AND FINANCE ❖ Volume 18 Number 3 interest on TIO balances and Treasury repurchase agreements fell below 25 basis points. In that environment, it was more remu- nerative for the Treasury to keep its money in the TGA. Shifting Treasury balances to private depositories would have increased the reserve balances of depository institutions and required the Fed to pay interest on those reserve balances (at the IOER rate of 25 basis points per annum). This would have reduced Federal Reserve payments to the Treasury (of Federal Reserve earnings in excess of expenses) by more than what the Treasury could earn from the depositories.32 In addition, a large TGA balance
  • 39. limited the risk that the Treasury might overdraw the account at a time when expenditures were extraordinarily volatile. At the same time, the volatile swings in TGA balances associ- ated with the decision to keep essentially all of the Treasury’s operating cash balances in the TGA (see Chart 2) did not cause a problem for the Fed because the swings did not result in any comparable volatility in the federal funds rate. In particular, expanding TGA balances did not reduce the quantity of reserves available to the banking system to a level at all close to what banks wanted or were required to hold and thus did not put upward pressure on the funds rate. Consequences for the Supplementary Financing Program In principle, paying interest on reserves could have led the Treasury to terminate the Supplementary Financing Program. Adhering to its November 17, 2008, announcement, the Treasury 32 However, the Treasury continued to keep $2 billion in TT&L accounts until December 29, 2011, to ensure that the functionalities of the TT&L program remained intact in the event that the Fed returned to the pre- crisis structure of monetary policy. By 2012, collector and retainer designations were eliminated, and the TT&L investment program was shut down. Treasury indicated that it planned on implementing a new investment program when market conditions warranted and that more details would be announced when they became available. did reduce the size of the program, but it did not eliminate it
  • 40. entirely (Chart 4). There were several reasons for not eliminating the Supple- mentary Financing Program at the end of 2008. First, SFP bills soaked up a nontrivial quantity of excess reserves.33 Second, higher SFP balances, like higher TGA balances, reduced the volume of reserves on which the Federal Reserve had to pay interest and were, therefore, fiscally beneficial to the Treasury. And third, the Supplementary Financing Program provided market participants with additional quantities of a short-term, credit risk–free instrument that was unusually attractive in the midst of the crisis.34 Conclusion The Treasury Tax and Loan Note program has long been an exemplar of cooperation between the Federal Reserve and the Treasury, with the Fed serving as the Treasury’s fi scal agent in maintaining the Treasury General Account and with the Treasury issuing cash calls and making direct investments to stabilize the TGA at a specifi ed target level. The 2008-09 crisis triggered a further deepening of the close relationship between the two institutions. When the Fed’s balance sheet ballooned in September 2008 as the crisis deepened, the Treasury announced, at the Fed’s request, the Supplementary Financ- ing Program to soak up excess reserves and to keep the federal funds rate from being driven down to zero. The subsequent introduction of interest on reserves left the Treasury free to abandon those aspects of the TT&L program aimed at stabi- lizing the TGA and allowed it to pursue cash management practices that, in light of the new monetary regime, were in the best interest of taxpayers. The Treasury’s cash management and investment strategy continues to evolve, guided by the goals of earning a fair return on investment, ensuring that the funds available in the TGA are suffi cent to avoid an overdraft, and avoiding interference with
  • 41. the implementation of monetary policy. When the interest rates that the Treasury receives on investments are higher, it may resume investing its surplus funds with the private sector, as it did prior to 2009. However, if short-term interest rates remain close to cur- rent levels and there is no need to target the TGA, then Treasury investments are likely to remain low or nonexistent since holding funds in the TGA is more remunerative than investing funds with the private sector. Nevertheless, a signifi cant decline in excess reserves resulting from a shift in monetary policy may once again make it necessary to target a more stable TGA, so that TGA volatility does not cause 33 Bernanke (2009) observed that “issuance of [SFP] bills effectively drains reserves from the banking system, improving monetary control.” 34 Hrung and Seligman (2011, p. 7) noted that “an incidental by-product” of the SFP program “was that it increased the amount of high-quality collateral available in the market, helping to alleviate . . . supply-side stresses in the money markets. . . .” Sources: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System; Federal Reserve Bank of New York. Note: The IOER rate is the interest rate on excess reserves.
  • 42. Chart 8 IOER Rate and Federal Funds Rate Percent IOER rate Federal funds rate 0 0.05 0.10 0.15 0.20 0.25 0.30 0.35 20102009 www.newyorkfed.org/research/cur rent_issues 9 undesirable federal funds rate volatility and interfere with the implementation of monetary policy. The author thanks Kenneth Garbade for his many substantive
  • 43. contributions to the preparation of this article. He also thanks David Monroe, Warren Hrung, John Partlan, Gregory Till, and Chris Burke for helpful comments on earlier versions. References Adrian, Tobias, Christopher Burke, and James McAndrews. 2009. “The Federal Reserve’s Primary Dealer Credit Facility.” Federal Reserve Bank of New York Current Issues in Economics and Finance 15, no. 4 (August). Adrian, Tobias, Karin Kimbrough, and Dina Marchioni. 2011. “The Federal Reserve’s Commercial Paper Funding Facility.” Federal Reserve Bank of New York Economic Policy Review 17, no. 1 (May): 25-39. Armantier, Olivier, Sandra Krieger, and James McAndrews. 2008. “The Federal Reserve’s Term Auction Facility.” Federal Reserve Bank of New York Current Issues in Economics and Finance 14, no. 5 (July). Bernanke, Ben. 2009. The Crisis and the Policy Response. Stamp Lecture, London School of Economics, London, England, January 13. Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. 2005. The Federal Reserve System: Purposes and Functions. Brockschmidt, Peggy. 1975. “Treasury Cash Balances.” Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City Monthly Review 60, no. 7 (July-August): 12-20. Federal Reserve Bank of New York. 2009. Domestic Open
  • 44. Market Operations during 2008. Available at www.newyorkfed.org/markets/omo/omo2008.pdf. Fleming, Michael, Warren Hrung, and Frank Keane. 2009. “The Term Securities Lending Facility: Origin, Design, and Effects.” Federal Reserve Bank of New York Current Issues in Economics and Finance 15, no. 2 (February). Gagnon, Joseph, Matthew Raskin, Julie Remache, and Brian Sack. “Large-Scale Asset Purchases by the Federal Reserve: Did They Work?” Federal Reserve Bank of New York Economic Policy Review 17, no. 1 (May): 41-59. The views expressed in this article are those of the authors and do not necessarily refl ect the position of the Federal Reserve Bank of New York or the Federal Reserve System. Current Issues in Economics and Finance is published by the Research and Statistics Group of the Federal Reserve Bank of New York. Linda Goldberg and Thomas Klitgaard are the editors. Editorial Staff: Valerie LaPorte, Mike De Mott, Michelle Bailer, Karen Carter, Anna Snider Production: Carol Perlmutter, David Rosenberg, Jane Urry Subscriptions to Current Issues are free. Send an e-mail to [email protected] or write to the Publications Function, Federal Reserve Bank of New York, 33 Liberty Street, New York, N.Y. 10045-0001. Back issues of Current Issues are available
  • 45. at http://www.newyorkfed.org/research/current_issues/. ABOUT THE AUTHORS Paul J. Santoro is a senior fi nancial/economic analyst in the Market Operations, Monitoring, and Analysis Function of the Federal Reserve Bank of New York’s Markets Group. Garbade, Kenneth, Frank Keane, Lorie Logan, Amanda Stokes, and Jennifer Wolgemuth. 2010. “The Introduction of the TMPG Fails Charge for U.S. Treasury Securities.” Federal Reserve Bank of New York Economic Policy Review 16, no. 2 (October): 45-71. Garbade, Kenneth, John Partlan, and Paul Santoro. 2004. “Recent Innovations in Treasury Cash Management.” Federal Reserve Bank of New York Current Issues in Economics and Finance 10, no. 11 (November). Goldberg, Linda, Craig Kennedy, and Jason Miu. 2011. “Central Bank Dollar Swap Lines and Overseas Dollar Funding Costs.” Federal Reserve Bank of New York Economic Policy Review 17, no. 1 (May): 3-20. Government Accountability Offi ce. 2007. Debt Management: Treasury Has Improved Short-Term Investment Programs, but Should Broaden Investments to Reduce Risks and Increase Returns. GAO-07-1105. Hrung, Warren. 2007. “An Examination of Treasury Term Investment Interest
  • 46. Rates.” Federal Reserve Bank of New York Economic Policy Review 13, no. 1 (March): 19-32. Hrung, Warren, and Jason Seligman. 2011. “Responses to the Financial Crisis, Treasury Debt, and the Impact on Short-Term Money Markets.” Federal Reserve Bank of New York Staff Reports, no. 481, January. Investment Company Institute. 2009. Report of the Money Market Working Group. Lang, Richard. 1979. “TTL Note Accounts and the Money Supply Process.” Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Review 61, no. 1 (October): 3-14. Lovett, Joan. 1978. “Treasury Tax and Loan Accounts and Federal Reserve Open Market Operations.” Federal Reserve Bank of New York Quarterly Review 3, no. 2 (summer): 41-6. Manypenny, Gerald D., and Michael L. Bermudez. 1992. “The Federal Reserve Banks as Fiscal Agents and Depositories of the United States.” Federal Reserve Bulletin 78, no. 10 (October): 727-37. McDonough, William. 1976. “New Policy Prompts Increased Defensive Operations by Federal Reserve.” Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas Business Review, March: 8-12.
  • 47. Special Inspector General for the Troubled Asset Relief Program. 2009. Initial Report to the Congress, February 6. 10 CURRENT ISSUES IN ECONOMICS AND FINANCE ❖ Volume 18 Number 3 RELATED READINGS FROM THE FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF NEW YORK’S RESEARCH GROUP Articles and Papers The Federal Reserve’s Commercial Paper Funding Facility Tobias Adrian, Karin Kimbrough, and Dina Marchioni Economic Policy Review, vol. 17, no. 1, May 2011 Established in the wake of Lehman Brothers’ bankruptcy to stabilize severe disruptions in the commercial paper market, the Commercial Paper Funding Facility allowed the Federal Reserve to act as a lender of last resort for issuers of commercial paper, thereby effectively addressing temporary liquidity distortions and alleviating the severe funding stress that threatened to further exacerbate the fi nancial crisis. In doing so, the facility proved to be a noteworthy model of liquidity provision in a market-based fi nancial system, where maturity transformation occurs outside of the commercial banking sector. This study examines the creation and performance of the facility, while outlining the evolution and importance of the commercial paper market. The Federal Reserve’s Primary Dealer Credit Facility Tobias Adrian, Christopher Burke, and James McAndrews
  • 48. Current Issues in Economics and Finance, vol. 15, no. 4, August 2009 As liquidity conditions in the “repo market”—the market where broker-dealers obtain fi nancing for their securities—deterio- rated following the near-bankruptcy of Bear Stearns in March 2008, the Federal Reserve took the step of creating a special facility to provide overnight loans to dealers that have a trading relationship with the Federal Reserve Bank of New York. Six months later, in the wake of new strains in the repo market, the Fed expanded the facility by broadening the types of collateral accepted for loans. Both initiatives were designed to help restore the orderly functioning of the market and to prevent the spill- over of distress to other fi nancial fi rms. The Term Securities Lending Facility: Origin, Design, and Effects Michael Fleming, Warren Hrung, and Frank Keane Current Issues in Economics and Finance, vol. 15, no. 2, February 2009 The Federal Reserve launched the Term Securities Lending Facility (TSLF) in 2008 to promote liquidity in the funding markets and improve the operation of the broader fi nancial markets. The facility increases the ability of dealers to obtain cash in the private market by enabling them to pledge securities temporarily as collateral for Treasuries, which are relatively easy to fi nance. The TSLF thus reduces the need for dealers to sell assets into illiquid markets and lessens the likelihood of a loss of confi dence among lenders. The Federal Reserve’s Term Auction Facility Olivier Armantier, Sandra Krieger, and James McAndrews Current Issues in Economics and Finance, vol. 14, no. 5, July
  • 49. 2008 As liquidity conditions in the term funding markets grew increasingly strained in late 2007, the Federal Reserve began making funds avail- able directly to banks through a new tool, the Term Auction Facility (TAF). The TAF provides term funding on a collateralized basis, at interest rates and amounts set by auction. The facility is designed to improve liquidity by making it easier for sound institutions to borrow when the markets are not operating effi ciently. Large-Scale Asset Purchases by the Federal Reserve: Did They Work? Joseph Gagnon, Matthew Raskin, Julie Remache, and Brian Sack Economic Policy Review, vol. 17, no. 1, May 2011 This study reviews the Federal Reserve’s experience in imple- menting large-scale asset purchases between late 2008 and March 2010. The authors show that by reducing the net supply of assets with long maturities, the purchases led to economi- cally meaningful and long-lasting reductions in longer term interest rates on a range of securities. The reductions primarily refl ect lower risk premiums, including term premiums. The asset purchase programs had an especially powerful effect on longer term interest rates on agency debt and agency mortgage-backed securities by improving market liquidity and removing assets with high prepayment risk from private portfolios. The Introduction of the TMPG Fails Charge
  • 50. for U.S. Treasury Securities Kenneth Garbade, Frank Keane, Lorie Logan, Amanda Stokes, and Jennifer Wolgemuth Economic Policy Review, vol. 16, no. 2, October 2010 The TPMG fails charge for U.S. Treasury securities provides that a buyer of Treasury securities can claim monetary compensa- tion from the seller if the seller fails to deliver the securities on a timely basis. The charge was introduced in May 2009 and replaced an existing market convention of simply postpon- ing—without any explicit penalty and at an unchanged invoice price—a seller’s obligation to deliver Treasury securities of the seller fails to deliver the securities on a scheduled settlement date. This article explains how a proliferation of settlement fails following the insolvency of Lehman Brothers Holdings Inc. in September 2008 led the Treasury Market Practices Group (TPMG), a group of market professionals committed to sup- porting the integrity and effi ciency of the U.S. Treasury market, to promote a change in the existing market convention. The change—the introduction of the fails charge—was signifi cant www.newyorkfed.org/research/cur rent_issues 11 because it mitigated an important dysfunctionality in the secondary market for U.S. Treasury securities and because it stands as an example of the value of cooperation between the public and private sectors in responding to altered market conditions in a fl exible, timely, and innovative fashion. Recent Innovations in Treasury Cash Management Kenneth Garbade, John Partlan, and Paul Santoro
  • 51. Current Issues in Economics and Finance, vol. 10, no. 11, November 2004 The Treasury Tax and Loan program, a joint undertaking of the Treasury and the Federal Reserve, is designed to manage federal tax receipts and stabilize the supply of reserves in the banking system. Three recent innovations—electronic collec- tion of business taxes, real-time investment of excess Treasury balances, and competitive bidding for Treasury deposits—have materially enhanced the ability of the two agencies to achieve these objectives. An Examination of Treasury Term Investment Interest Rates Warren Hrung Economic Policy Review, vol. 13, no. 1, March 2007 In November 2003, the Term Investment Option (TIO) program became an offi cial cash management tool of the U.S. Treasury Department. Through TIO, the Treasury lends funds to banks for a set number of days at an interest rate determined by a single-rate auction. One reason why the Treasury introduced TIO was to try to earn a market rate of return on its excess cash balances. This article studies 166 TIO auctions from November 2003 to February 2006 to determine how TIO interest rates have compared with market rates. The author investigates the spread between TIO rates and rates on mortgage-backed-security repos, a close benchmark for TIO rates. He fi nds that aside from offerings with very short-term lengths, the Treasury receives an interest rate on TIO auctions comparable to market rates. He also documents a negative relationship between an auction’s size and the spread between TIO and repo rates. Furthermore, the Treasury’s announcement and auctioning of funds on the same day does not adversely affect rate spreads, a fi nding that suggests that banks are indifferent to more advance notice of TIO auctions.
  • 52. Responses to the Financial Crisis, Treasury Debt, and the Impact on Short-Term Money Markets Warren Hrung and Jason Seligman Staff Reports, no. 481, January 2011 Several programs have been introduced by U.S. fi scal and monetary authorities in response to the fi nancial crisis. This study examines the responses involving Treasury debt—the Term Securities Lending Facility (TSLF), the Supplemental Financing Program, increases in Treasury issuance, and open market operations—and their impacts on the overnight Treasury general collateral repo rate, a key money market rate. The authors’ contribution is to consider each policy in light of the others, both to help guide policy responses to future crises and to empha- size policy interactions. Only the TSLF was designed to directly address stresses in short-term money markets by temporarily changing the supply of Treasury collateral in the marketplace. We fi nd that the TSLF is uniquely effective relative to other policies and that, while changes in Treasury collateral do affect repo rates, the impacts are not equivalent across sources of Treasury collateral. Central Bank Dollar Swap Lines and Overseas Dollar Funding Costs Linda Goldberg, Craig Kennedy, and Jason Miu Economic Policy Review, vol. 17, no. 1, May 2011 In the decade prior to the fi nancial crisis, foreign banks’ exposure to U.S.-dollar-denominated assets increased dramatically. When the crisis hit in 2007, the banks’ access to dollar funding came under severe constraints. The Federal Reserve responded in
  • 53. December 2007 by establishing temporary reciprocal currency swap lines with foreign central banks designed to ameliorate the dollar funding stresses overseas. Drawing on rigorous analysis of the swaps, as well as insights of other economic studies and anecdotal accounts of market participants, this article concludes that the lines were effective in reducing both dollar funding costs abroad and stresses in the money markets. Liberty Street Economics Blog Posts Innovations in Treasury Debt Instruments Kenneth Garbade April 9, 2012 Will “Quantitative Easing” Trigger Infl ation? Kenneth Garbade June 8, 2011 Will the Federal Reserve’s Asset Purchases Lead to Higher Infl ation? Jamie McAndrews May 18, 2011