SlideShare a Scribd company logo
1 of 89
D
e
liv
e
re
d
b
y
P
u
b
lis
h
in
g
T
e
ch
n
o
lo
g
y
Io
w
a
S
ta
te
U
n
iv
e
rs
ity
1
2
9
.1
8
6
.1
.5
5
T
u
e
,
0
9
S
e
p
2
0
1
4
1
4
:3
5
:2
5
C
o
p
yr
ig
h
t
M
o
h
r
S
ie
b
e
ck
38
The Effect of Contract Regulation on Franchising
by
Jonathan Klick, Bruce H. Kobayashi, and Larry E. Ribstein∗
Previous work on the regulation of termination clauses in
franchise contracts has
ignored the ability of parties to contract around state law. Using
data on two na-
tional fast-food restaurants, we find that Washington, D.C.’s
termination restric-
tion which did not restrict choice-of-law provisions had little
systematic effect on
business practice, while Iowa’s termination restriction which
did prohibit choice-
of-law provisions had a large negative effect on franchising.
(JEL: D86, K12, K20,
L14)
1 Introduction
Franchising is an important and frequently studied form of
organization. Prior
articles have used the franchising form to examine the general
nature of intra-
versus interfirm contracting1 and to analyze how contracts and
incentives are used
to reduce transaction and agency costs. Paul Rubin (1978)
applied the insights of
transaction cost economics to explain the existence of
franchising as a business
form. Rubin argued that existing explanations for use of the
franchise form based on
capital constraints were implausible, and that insights from
Coase’s (1937) theory
of the firm better explain the existence of the franchise form. In
addition, studies
of franchise regulation illustrate how the regulation of the
contractual relationship
between franchisors and franchisees affects contracting and the
organization of
firms.2
∗ Jonathan Klick (corresponding author), University of
Pennsylvania Law School;
Bruce Kobayashi, George Mason University School of Law; and
Larry Ribstein, Uni-
versity of Illinois College of Law. We thank Ted Eisenberg and
Andreas Roider as
well as the other participants at the 2011 JITE conference on
“Testing Contracts.”
1 See Klein (1995) (discussing the economics of franchise
contracts); Lafontaine
and Masten (1995) (discussing literature generally); Brickley,
Misra, and Van Horn
(2006) (finding contract duration in franchise contracts is
positively related to fran-
chisee’s level of specific investments), Brickley (1999)
(examining incidence of spe-
cific contractual provisions in franchise contracts).
2 See, e.g., Brickley, Dark, and Weisbach (1991), Muris and
Beales (1994) (exam-
ining state regulation of termination); Marvel (1995)
(examining FTC regulation of
gasoline franchising); Smith (1982) (examining state regulation
of automobile dealers).
Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics
JITE 168 (2012), 38–53 © 2012 Mohr Siebeck – ISSN 0932-
4569
D
e
liv
e
re
d
b
y
P
u
b
lis
h
in
g
T
e
ch
n
o
lo
g
y
Io
w
a
S
ta
te
U
n
iv
e
rs
ity
1
2
9
.1
8
6
.1
.5
5
T
u
e
,
0
9
S
e
p
2
0
1
4
1
4
:3
5
:2
5
C
o
p
yr
ig
h
t
M
o
h
r
S
ie
b
e
ck
The Effect of Contract Regulation on Franchising(2012) 39
The use of termination clauses has been central in much of this
literature. Rubin
(1978) and Klein (1995) both argue that termination clauses
serve as part of a bond
whereby a franchisee risks losing his rents if he engages in ex
post opportunism.
Brickley, Dark, and Weisbach (1991) test this idea using state
laws that restrict
termination clauses, generally finding support for the bonding
hypothesis. However,
this study relies on cross-sectional comparisons from which it is
difficult to make
causal inferences. Further, as we suggested in Klick, Kobayashi,
and Ribstein (2009),
it is surprising that these laws, on their own, have any effect on
franchise activity
given the ability of parties to contract around termination
restrictions in many cases.
In this article, we address both of these issues using some
limited data on fran-
chising in the fast-food industry. Using panel data, we examine
the effects of the
termination restriction law passed in Iowa in 1992 and the
removal of a similar law
in the District of Columbia in 1998. Panel data provide the
opportunity to parse
out idiosyncratic differences across states in isolating the effect
of a given law in
ways not possible in purely cross-sectional data. Also, these two
particular laws
are interesting in that the Iowa law severely restricted the
ability of the parties to
contract around the termination limitation, while the D.C. law,
when it was in effect,
did not foreclose the possibility of waiver or choice-of-law-and-
forum clauses.
Our examination of the effects of these law changes suggests
that the Iowa law
did affect the degree of franchise activity that occurred in Iowa.
Given the high
transaction costs created by restrictions on clauses that would
undo the termina-
tion law, the termination restriction appears to have reduced
franchise activity. The
D.C. termination law, on the other hand, which had no such
restrictions, had am-
biguous effects on franchising in the jurisdiction. This leaves
open the possibility
that parties simply contracted around the law, as would be
suggested by the Coase
theorem.
On a methodological note, because our analysis focuses on very
limited variation
in the legal variable that provides our statistical identification,
we explore a number
of new methods for making statistical inferences. While these
tools have yet to
have much of an impact in the empirical law and economics
literature, they deserve
attention since the problems we face are quite common when
investigating the
effects of legal changes.
In section 2, we briefly review the economic theory regarding
the use of termina-
tion clauses in franchise contract and we describe the existing
empirical evidence
regarding their effects. In section 3, we describe the panel data
we collected. Sec-
tion 4 presents our empirical results, while section 5 discusses
the problem of
statistical inference in these settings. We conclude in section 6.
2 Termination Clauses in Franchise Contracts
As laid out in Rubin (1978) and Klein (1995), franchise
contracts give rise to
problems of opportunism. Poor performance on the part of a
given franchisee
generates a negative externality borne by the franchisor and
other franchisees. This
D
e
liv
e
re
d
b
y
P
u
b
lis
h
in
g
T
e
ch
n
o
lo
g
y
Io
w
a
S
ta
te
U
n
iv
e
rs
ity
1
2
9
.1
8
6
.1
.5
5
T
u
e
,
0
9
S
e
p
2
0
1
4
1
4
:3
5
:2
5
C
o
p
yr
ig
h
t
M
o
h
r
S
ie
b
e
ck
J. Klick, B. H. Kobayashi, and L. E. Ribstein40 JITE 168
negative externality degrades the value of the trademark. Ex
ante, franchisees would
like to commit to a given level of performance, but this
commitment is not credible.
In order to make the commitment credible, the franchisee posts
a bond through the
payment of a franchise fee and makes other sunk investments,
while agreeing to
broad termination rights for the franchisor. In expectation, these
expenditures will
be recouped through a flow of future rents.
As made clear in Klein (1995) as long as the net present
discounted value of these
future rents exceeds the gain available from cheating (i.e., poor
performance), the
franchisee will not shirk under these conditions, assuming the
franchisor detects
cheating perfectly. In the case where detection is imperfect, the
size of the bond and
sunk investments can be scaled to offset the detection problem.
However, these broad termination rights may create an
opportunism problem on
the part of the franchisor. Specifically, the franchisor can
engage in cream skimming
in which it terminates contracts when a given franchise proves
to be unexpectedly
profitable for the franchisee. In such a scenario, the franchisor
can resell the unit at
terms more favorable to itself or run the unit directly. While
reputational concerns
may constrain this franchisor opportunism, if franchisees are
poorly informed or
make systematic mistakes, termination clauses may trade one
form of opportunism
for another.
This cream-skimming concern has motivated a number of
jurisdictions to restrict
such clauses, requiring a showing of good cause for termination
on the part of fran-
chisors. If the termination clauses serve to reign in franchisee
opportunism, limiting
termination to good cause is likely to leave some opportunism
unchecked in a world
of incomplete contracts, litigation costs, and court error. On the
margin, some fran-
chise units will become economically unprofitable, leading the
franchisor to reduce
its activity, reducing social welfare in the process.3 If the
cream-skimming concern
is dominant, however, these laws could improve social welfare
by constraining the
franchisor’s opportunism.
If these laws primarily serve to limit franchisor opportunism,
the effect on fran-
chising activity is ambiguous. If franchisees no longer fear ex
post opportunism on
the part of franchisors, they could be willing to open more
franchises at a given set
of terms. However, if the opportunism took the form of tricking
franchisees into
opening many poor locations in the hope of discovering a few
unexpected prizes,
termination restrictions could lead to a reduction of franchising.
To test these competing hypotheses, Brickley, Dark, and
Weisbach (1991) com-
pare the extent of franchising in states that restrict termination
and those that do
not. They find a lower share of franchising in restricted states
than in non-restricted
states using cross-sectional data. To address the efficiency
question, they sepa-
rately analyze industries serving primarily non-repeat customers
(where franchisee
3 Some units might be run by the franchisor at a lower, but still
positive, profit.
However, as in the Klein model, some units that cannot be run
profitably by the fran-
chisor due to its inability to control agency costs could be run
profitably by a well
incentivized franchisee whose opportunism is constrained. Once
this constraint is re-
duced, the unit becomes unprofitably regardless of which entity
manages it.
D
e
liv
e
re
d
b
y
P
u
b
lis
h
in
g
T
e
ch
n
o
lo
g
y
Io
w
a
S
ta
te
U
n
iv
e
rs
ity
1
2
9
.1
8
6
.1
.5
5
T
u
e
,
0
9
S
e
p
2
0
1
4
1
4
:3
5
:2
5
C
o
p
yr
ig
h
t
M
o
h
r
S
ie
b
e
ck
The Effect of Contract Regulation on Franchising(2012) 41
opportunism is more likely to be a problem), finding the effect
to be more pro-
nounced in these industries. This suggests that franchisee
opportunism concerns
dominate concerns over cream skimming, and the termination
restrictions affect
organizational form. The restrictions then presumably have a
negative effect on
economic efficiency. They find complementary evidence using
cross-sectional firm-
level data.
Cross-sectional studies, however, have significant limitations
due to omitted vari-
able biases. Specifically, law passage may be endogenous to
other factors that
affect franchising patterns. Modern panel data techniques,
specifically differences-
in-differences studies using fixed effects, can mitigate these
concerns. If the portion
of the omitted variables that is the source of the bias is time-
invariant, this kind of
research design can yield causal inferences. Brickley, Dark, and
Weisbach (1991)
could not implement such a design because of data limitations.
Even if the omitted
variable bias is generated by changing unobservable
characteristics of a state, if those
changes are linear, the bias can be controlled through the
inclusion of state-specific
trends.
Another concern with the termination law analysis involves the
ability of par-
ties to contract around such laws. Brickley (2002) suggests that
some contractual
changes do occur in the face of these laws, finding that
franchisors located in states
with restrictions tend to use lower front-end fees and higher
royalties, presumably
spending more to monitor franchisee behavior. Again, these
results are based only
on cross-sectional data, so causal inference is problematic.
However, even if the effects are causal, they are presumably not
the parties’
first response to termination restrictions. Namely, as discussed
above and in Klick,
Kobayashi, and Ribstein (2009), in some states it would be
simple to contractually
avoid the effect of the statutory termination restrictions.
Although states generally do
not permit direct waiver of these restrictions, which are
intended for the protection
of one of the contracting parties, parties can achieve a similar
effect through a clause
providing that the contract is to be interpreted and enforced
under the law of a state
that does not regulate franchise termination. Under applicable
choice-of-law rules,
whether a court will enforce a choice-of-law clause depends on
the contacts between
the parties and transaction on the one hand and the chosen
jurisdiction on the other,
whether a state with closer contacts seeks to regulate the
transaction, and on the
nature of this regulation (O’Hara and Ribstein, 2009, ch. 3).
Because courts have
significant discretion under these rules whether to enforce
another state’s restrictions,
the parties might maximize the chance that the clause will be
enforced by adding
clauses to the agreement providing that the dispute will be
decided by a court that
is likely to enforce the parties’ choice-of-law clause, and that
the parties consent to
jurisdiction in the designated forum.
Enforceability of such choice-of-forum and jurisdiction clauses
has been sup-
ported by the U.S. Supreme Court.4 Indeed, the Court’s 1985
ruling enforcing
4 M/S Bremen v. Zapata Off-Shore Co., 407 U.S. 1 (1972);
Carnival Cruise Lines,
Inc. v. Shute, 499 U.S. 585 (1991).
D
e
liv
e
re
d
b
y
P
u
b
lis
h
in
g
T
e
ch
n
o
lo
g
y
Io
w
a
S
ta
te
U
n
iv
e
rs
ity
1
2
9
.1
8
6
.1
.5
5
T
u
e
,
0
9
S
e
p
2
0
1
4
1
4
:3
5
:2
5
C
o
p
yr
ig
h
t
M
o
h
r
S
ie
b
e
ck
J. Klick, B. H. Kobayashi, and L. E. Ribstein42 JITE 168
a consent-to-jurisdiction clause in a franchise contract5
provided an important im-
petus to the enforcement of choice-of-forum and choice-of-law
clauses in these
contracts. U.S. federal courts quickly followed with cases
enforcing choice-of-law
clauses in these contracts.6 States could avoid the effect of
these rulings by enacting
statutory provisions explicitly voiding choice-of-law and
choice-of-forum clauses.
However, only two states, Washington and Iowa, void both
types of provisions
in their franchise protection statutes.7 Parties could avoid
regulation of franchises
located in other states by choosing the law of a non-regulating
state and a forum
that will enforce the contract’s choice-of-forum clause. Even if
the franchisor is
located in a state that does not enforce choice-of-law or choice-
of-forum clauses,
the franchisor can avoid the effect of franchise regulation of
franchises located in
states that do enforce the clauses (Klick, Kobayashi, and
Ribstein, 2009).
Use of choice-of-law-and-forum clauses is distinct from other
types of contractual
or organizational responses in that it does not require the firm
to make costly
tradeoffs. The effect of choice-of-law-and-forum clauses stems
from inherent limits
on states’ regulatory powers in a federal system, and can
produce results closer
to pure regulatory arbitrage than the courts in the regulating
state are likely to
permit under that state’s law (Kobayashi and Ribstein, 1999).
The prior economics
literature had completely ignored this availability of regulatory
arbitrage.
Given the parties’ ability to contract around termination
restrictions using choice-
of-law and choice-of-forum clauses, it would be surprising if
such laws, on their
own, would have any effect on franchise activity. Franchise
contracts routinely
contain contractual choice-of-law-and-forum clauses, and the
courts have allowed
such choices when not explicitly precluded by a state
(Kobayashi and Ribstein,
1999; Klick, Kobayashi, and Ribstein, 2009). Our earlier
empirical work in this
area suggests the effectiveness of contractual choice of
jurisdiction as a mechanism
for regulatory arbitrage. Taking into account state variation in
restricting choice-of-
law-and-forum clauses, we found that termination restrictions
only have an effect
if the states’ statutes explicitly restrict use of contractual
choice-of-law-and-forum
clauses (Klick, Kobayashi, and Ribstein, 2009).
Our previous work in this area uses panel data methods to
mitigate the endo-
geneity concerns of the existing economics literature and it does
allow for a more
complete consideration of the heterogeneity in the strictness of
the state termination
restrictions. However, it relies on a fairly blunt metric of
franchise activity, namely
employment in industries with a high degree of franchising in
them. In this article,
we instead rely on firm-level franchising data.
To address the issue of legal heterogeneity, we focus on two
very different termi-
nation restrictions. First we examine the termination restriction
introduced in Iowa in
5 Burger King v. Rudzewicz, 471 U.S. 462 (1985).
6 Tele-Save Merchandising v. Consumers Distributing, 814 F.2d
1120 (6th Cir.
1987); Modern Computer Systems, Inc. v. Modern Banking
Systems, Inc., 871 F.2d 734
(8th Cir. 1989).
7 For a comprehensive listing of State Franchise Protection
Statutes, see Klick,
Kobayashi, and Ribstein (2009, Table 1).
D
e
liv
e
re
d
b
y
P
u
b
lis
h
in
g
T
e
ch
n
o
lo
g
y
Io
w
a
S
ta
te
U
n
iv
e
rs
ity
1
2
9
.1
8
6
.1
.5
5
T
u
e
,
0
9
S
e
p
2
0
1
4
1
4
:3
5
:2
5
C
o
p
yr
ig
h
t
M
o
h
r
S
ie
b
e
ck
The Effect of Contract Regulation on Franchising(2012) 43
1992 which also included restrictions on waiver, choice-of-law,
and choice-of-forum
clauses. These additional restrictions make it very difficult to
avoid the termination
restriction through contractual mechanisms, presumably leading
to a relatively large
change in franchising behavior. We also examine the federal
repeal of Washington,
D.C.’s termination restriction in 1998. The D.C. law was not
one of the few jurisdic-
tions restricting parties’ ability to avoid regulation through
waiver, choice-of-law,
or choice-of-forum clauses (see Klick, Kobayashi, and Ribstein,
2009, Table 1).8
Presumably then, if termination clauses serve some economic
purpose, the parties
could have easily contracted around the restriction through one
of these other av-
enues, suggesting that any change in franchising behavior
occurring after repeal
would likely be small.
Unfortunately, we have no way of testing the efficiency effects
of any of these
laws, lacking a comparison between repeat and non-repeat
businesses. Instead, we
merely aim to provide a better design for causal inference and
to highlight the
importance of more careful consideration of legal subtleties.
3 Franchising Data
The data used by Brickley, Dark, and Weisbach (1991) came
from the U.S. De-
partment of Commerce publication “Franchising in the
Economy.” These data were
not published beyond 1986, requiring us to find a different data
source for our
analysis.
We examined the Uniform Franchise Offering Circular (UFOC)
filed by a number
of fast-food franchisors with the Maryland Attorney General’s
Office. The UFOC
(since renamed the Franchise Disclosure Document), which is a
required filing in 15
states contains an item (item 20) that discloses the number of
outlets franchised and
franchisor operated in each state. Unfortunately, for our
purposes, this item was
only required beginning in 1992, although some franchisors
began disclosing this
information in the preceding years.
Of the large fast-food franchisors, the only ones that included
the information for
item 20 before 1992 were Burger King (disclosure beginning in
1990) and Domino’s
Pizza (disclosure beginning in 1989). We focus much of our
analysis on those two
franchisors. Because of its importance in the industry, we also
include McDonald’s
8 Both the Iowa and D.C. statutes required notice and good
cause for a franchise
to terminate its contract with a franchisee. Both statutes also
required cause for non-
renewal, and allowed a franchisee a right to cure defects. Thus,
with respect to the ter-
mination/renewal provisions, both the Iowa and D.C. statutes
were substantively simi-
lar. The Iowa statute did include other substantive provisions
not included in the D.C.
statute, including franchisor liability for encroachment and a
provision that allowed
a franchisor to purchase supplies, equipment, services, etc. from
sources of the fran-
chisee’s choosing. The encroachment provisions originally
enacted in the 1992 Iowa
statute were weakened in a 1995 amendment to the statute. See
Iowa Code § 523H
(1992, 1995).
D
e
liv
e
re
d
b
y
P
u
b
lis
h
in
g
T
e
ch
n
o
lo
g
y
Io
w
a
S
ta
te
U
n
iv
e
rs
ity
1
2
9
.1
8
6
.1
.5
5
T
u
e
,
0
9
S
e
p
2
0
1
4
1
4
:3
5
:2
5
C
o
p
yr
ig
h
t
M
o
h
r
S
ie
b
e
ck
J. Klick, B. H. Kobayashi, and L. E. Ribstein44 JITE 168
Table 1
Number of Franchised Units per State
Firm Mean St. dev. IA 1992 count DC 1998 count
Burger King 120 128 47 9
Domino’s Pizza 73 73 17 13
McDonald’s 188 188 88 27
Note: Data from UFOC item 20 filed with Maryland Attorney
General’s Office. Sample
covers 1990–2000 for Burger King, 1989–2000 for Domino’s
Pizza, and 1992–2000 for
McDonald’s.
(disclosure beginning in 1992) in our analysis of the D.C.
termination restriction.9
Descriptive statistics for these firms are presented in Table 1.
4 Contract Regulations (Sometimes) Affect Behavior
Our research design examines the number of franchised units in
a given state during
a given year, controlling for deflated state per capita income, as
well as state- and
year-fixed effects. We did examine other control variables,
primarily demographic
controls, we chose to omit them in the results presented because
(1) they did
not affect the results of interest and (2) because demographic
data are linearly
interpolated between census years, inclusion of these data in the
regressions is
unlikely to be informative beyond the specifications that also
include linear state-
specific trends.
Because of concerns regarding scale differences across states,
we present re-
gression specifications that use both the level and the natural
log of the dependent
variable. Our regressor of interest, the termination restriction, is
an indicator taking
the value of 1 if the state restricted the application of
termination clauses in fran-
chise contracts and 0 otherwise. To account for dependence in
our data, we cluster
standard errors at the state level. In our first set of results, we
pool the effect of the
Iowa and the Washington, D.C. restrictions in Table 2.
In addition to a general lack of statistical significance, it is
apparent that there is
no robust effect of the laws across the two firms we examined.
However, given the
discussion above about the importance of considering how firms
might be able to
contract around laws such as these, we proceed to examine the
two laws separately.
First we examine the highly restrictive Iowa law which
prohibits the application
of not only termination clauses, but it also explicitly prohibits
the application of
waiver, choice-of-law, and choice-of-forum clauses. We present
these results in
Table 3.10
9 We examined a number of other franchisors in the context of
the D.C. law, find-
ing qualitatively similar results to those that follow.
10 Note that the Table 3 and Table 4 regressions omit
observations from Washing-
ton, D.C. We do this to avoid the inclusion of any effects
arising from the D.C. termi-
nation restriction that will be examined later.
D
e
liv
e
re
d
b
y
P
u
b
lis
h
in
g
T
e
ch
n
o
lo
g
y
Io
w
a
S
ta
te
U
n
iv
e
rs
ity
1
2
9
.1
8
6
.1
.5
5
T
u
e
,
0
9
S
e
p
2
0
1
4
1
4
:3
5
:2
5
C
o
p
yr
ig
h
t
M
o
h
r
S
ie
b
e
ck
The Effect of Contract Regulation on Franchising(2012) 45
Table 2
Effect of Termination Restrictions on Franchised Restaurants
Burger King Domino’s Pizza
Franchise ln(franchise Franchise ln(franchise
units units) units units)
Termination 8.38 −0.08∗ ∗ ∗ −0.11 −0.11
restriction (19.53) (0.02) (5.17) (0.21)
State effects yes yes yes yes
Year effects yes yes yes yes
State trends no no no no
Notes: ∗ ∗ ∗ p < 0.01 (against two-sided test of zero effect);
∗ ∗ p < 0.05 (against two-sided
test of zero effect); ∗ p < 0.10 (against two-sided test of zero
effect); standard errors
in parentheses clustered at state level. Sample includes the 50
states and the District of
Columbia for the period 1990–2000 (n = 561) for Burger King
and 1989–2000 for Domi-
no’s Pizza (n = 612). Regressions control for constant state per
capita income. Franchise
data come from UFOC’s (item 20) filed with Maryland State
Attorney General’s Office.
Table 3
Effect of 1992 Iowa Termination Restriction on Franchised
Restaurants
Burger King Domino’s Pizza
Franchise ln(franchise Franchise ln(franchise
units units) units units)
Termination −22.59 −0.06 −7.14 −0.40
restriction (6.30)∗ ∗ ∗ (0.04) (3.50)∗ ∗ (0.04)∗ ∗ ∗
State effects yes yes yes yes
Year effects yes yes yes yes
State trends no no no no
Notes: ∗ ∗ ∗ p < 0.01 (against two-sided test of zero effect);
∗ ∗ p < 0.05 (against two-sided
test of zero effect); ∗ p < 0.10 (against two-sided test of zero
effect); standard errors in
parentheses clustered at state level. Sample includes the 50
states for the period 1990–2000
(n = 550) for Burger King and 1989–2000 for Domino’s Pizza
(n = 600). Regressions con-
trol for constant state per capita income. Franchise data come
from UFOC’s (item 20) filed
with Maryland State Attorney General’s Office.
We find that the effect of the Iowa law is uniformly negative
and the effect
is generally statistically significant for both firms in both the
log and the level
specifications. The point estimates suggest that the Iowa
restriction was associated
with a decline in Burger King franchises, relative to the Iowa
baseline and relative to
the amount of franchising occurring elsewhere, of about 46%.
For Domino’s Pizza,
the comparable magnitude is 33%.
While the fixed-effects model accounts for constant unobserved
heterogeneity
across states that could lead to omitted variables bias in pure
cross-sectional com-
D
e
liv
e
re
d
b
y
P
u
b
lis
h
in
g
T
e
ch
n
o
lo
g
y
Io
w
a
S
ta
te
U
n
iv
e
rs
ity
1
2
9
.1
8
6
.1
.5
5
T
u
e
,
0
9
S
e
p
2
0
1
4
1
4
:3
5
:2
5
C
o
p
yr
ig
h
t
M
o
h
r
S
ie
b
e
ck
J. Klick, B. H. Kobayashi, and L. E. Ribstein46 JITE 168
Table 4
Effect of 1992 Iowa Termination Restriction on Franchised
Restaurants:
Allowing for State Trends
Burger King Domino’s Pizza
Franchise ln(franchise Franchise ln(franchise
units units) units units)
Termination −8.31 −0.13 −15.70 −0.92
restriction (1.42)∗ ∗ ∗ (0.04)∗ ∗ ∗ (2.53)∗ ∗ ∗ (0.05)∗ ∗ ∗
State effects yes yes yes yes
Year effects yes yes yes yes
State trends yes yes yes yes
Notes: ∗ ∗ ∗ p < 0.01 (against two-sided test of zero effect);
∗ ∗ p < 0.05 (against two-sided
test of zero effect); ∗ p < 0.10 (against two-sided test of zero
effect); standard errors in
parentheses clustered at state level. Sample includes the 50
states for the period 1990–2000
(n = 550) for Burger King and 1989–2000 for Domino’s Pizza
(n = 600). Regressions con-
trol for constant state per capita income. Franchise data come
from UFOC’s (item 20) filed
with Maryland State Attorney General’s Office.
parisons, it does not account for changing heterogeneity that
could be associated
both with law adoption and franchising. To attempt to mitigate
this concern, we
present regressions that include linear state-specific trends in
Table 4.
Once again, we find uniformly negative and statistically
significant effects associ-
ated with the Iowa termination restriction, relative to Iowa’s
baseline and relative to
developments in franchising elsewhere. As for the endogeneity
concerns, the trend
specifications suggest, if anything, that the earlier results may
have actually been
understated.
Moving on to the Washington, D.C. termination restriction,
which was repealed
by the U.S. Congress in 1998, we note that compared to the
Iowa law, the D.C.
law is relatively easy to contract around since it contains no
explicit limitation on
waiver, choice-of-law, or choice-of-forum clauses. While it is
possible that a court
could read such limitations into any transaction, especially with
respect to waiver
clauses, it is by no means guaranteed.11 Because of this, we
predict that any effect
of the law is likely to be smaller and less precise than that
associated with the Iowa
law. We present the first set of D.C. results in Table 5.
In one case the effect of the D.C. law is of a different sign than
that associated with
the Iowa law passage. While this may be suggestive that the
D.C. law is different
in unexpected ways than the Iowa law, the sign difference
within the Burger King
specifications could be suggestive of a general lack of
robustness. We see more
evidence of this when we examine regressions that include
state-specific linear
trends in Table 6.
11 For a discussion of these issues, see Klick, Kobayashi, and
Ribstein (2009).
D
e
liv
e
re
d
b
y
P
u
b
lis
h
in
g
T
e
ch
n
o
lo
g
y
Io
w
a
S
ta
te
U
n
iv
e
rs
ity
1
2
9
.1
8
6
.1
.5
5
T
u
e
,
0
9
S
e
p
2
0
1
4
1
4
:3
5
:2
5
C
o
p
yr
ig
h
t
M
o
h
r
S
ie
b
e
ck
The Effect of Contract Regulation on Franchising(2012) 47
Table 5
Effect of 1998 D.C. Termination Restriction Repeal on
Franchised Restaurants
Burger King Domino’s Pizza
Franchise ln(franchise Franchise ln(franchise
units units) units units)
Termination 31.41 −0.11 6.77 0.17
restriction (5.36)∗ ∗ ∗ (0.03)∗ ∗ ∗ (2.93)∗ ∗ (0.03)∗ ∗ ∗
State effects yes yes yes yes
Year effects yes yes yes yes
State trends no no no no
Notes: ∗ ∗ ∗ p < 0.01 (against two-sided test of zero effect);
∗ ∗ p < 0.05 (against two-sided
test of zero effect); ∗ p < 0.10 (against two-sided test of zero
effect); standard errors in
parentheses clustered at state level. Sample includes 49 states
(Iowa is omitted) and the
District of Columbia for the period 1990–2000 (n = 550) for
Burger King and 1989–2000
for Domino’s Pizza (n = 600). Regressions control for constant
state per capita income.
Franchise data come from UFOC’s (item 20) filed with
Maryland State Attorney General’s
Office.
Table 6
Effect of 1998 D.C. Termination Restriction Repeal on
Franchised Restaurants:
Allowing for State Trends
Burger King Domino’s Pizza
Franchise ln(franchise Franchise ln(franchise
units units) units units)
Termination −3.51 −0.54 4.32 −0.05
restriction (1.70)∗ ∗ (0.03)∗ ∗ ∗ (1.79)∗ ∗ (0.05)
State effects yes yes yes yes
Year effects yes yes yes yes
State trends yes yes yes yes
Notes: ∗ ∗ ∗ p < 0.01 (against two-sided test of zero effect);
∗ ∗ p < 0.05 (against two-sided
test of zero effect); ∗ p < 0.10 (against two-sided test of zero
effect); standard errors in
parentheses clustered at state level. Sample includes 49 states
(Iowa is omitted) and the
District of Columbia for the period 1990–2000 (n = 550) for
Burger King and 1989–2000
for Domino’s Pizza (n = 600). Regressions control for constant
state per capita income.
Franchise data come from UFOC’s (item 20) filed with
Maryland State Attorney General’s
Office.
What is most evident is the lack of stability in the parameter
estimates. Between
Tables 5 and 6, we see large changes in the magnitude of the
coefficients as well
as sign changes. Within each table as well, there are indications
of fragility of the
estimates. We take this as weak evidence of the lesser effect of
the D.C. law, though,
D
e
liv
e
re
d
b
y
P
u
b
lis
h
in
g
T
e
ch
n
o
lo
g
y
Io
w
a
S
ta
te
U
n
iv
e
rs
ity
1
2
9
.1
8
6
.1
.5
5
T
u
e
,
0
9
S
e
p
2
0
1
4
1
4
:3
5
:2
5
C
o
p
yr
ig
h
t
M
o
h
r
S
ie
b
e
ck
J. Klick, B. H. Kobayashi, and L. E. Ribstein48 JITE 168
of course, it could also be a sign of model misspecification or
other empirical
problems.12
We see a similar lack of robustness if we examine the effect of
the D.C. law’s
repeal on the franchising activities of McDonald’s in Table 7.
Table 7
Effect of 1998 D.C. Termination Restriction Repeal on
Franchised
McDonald’s Restaurants
McDonald’s
Franchise ln(franchise Franchise ln(franchise
units units) units units)
Termination 26.94 0.07 −20.09 −0.22
restriction (5.30)∗ ∗ ∗ (0.02)∗ ∗ ∗ (4.20)∗ ∗ ∗ (0.02)∗ ∗ ∗
State effects yes yes yes yes
Year effects yes yes yes yes
State trends no no yes yes
Notes: ∗ ∗ ∗ p < 0.01 (against two-sided test of zero effect);
∗ ∗ p < 0.05 (against two-sided
test of zero effect); ∗ p < 0.10 (against two-sided test of zero
effect); standard errors in
parentheses clustered at state level. Sample includes 49 states
(Iowa is omitted) and the
District of Columbia for the period 1992–2000 (n = 450).
Regressions control for constant
state per capita income. Franchise data come from UFOC’s
(item 20) filed with Maryland
State Attorney General’s Office.
From these analyses, the best estimate is that the Iowa
termination restriction
had a significantly negative, in terms of both statistical
significance and economic
importance, effect on franchising, while the weaker D.C. law
did not have a clear
effect. This is consistent with the notion that contractual
regulations only bite when
it is difficult to contract around them. This point may seem
trivial, but it is one that
has been missed in the voluminous economics literature on
franchising.
While we believe we have made methodological and substantive
improvements
in the analysis in this field, our data do not allow us to
investigate the economic
efficiency of termination clauses or laws that disallow them.
The laws do seem
to affect economic behavior when they increase the costs of
contracting around
them.
12 As Roider (2012) makes clear, failure to account for trends
can be a source of
misspecification. Our primary concern here is the lack of a
uniform effect of the law
in terms of sign both across firms and across specifications.
This kind of fragility sug-
gests that we cannot make an inference about the effect of the
law with any degree of
confidence. Eisenberg (2012) suggests, based on graphical
analyses, that the problem
may be one of a failure to find decent counterfactuals in the
available data.
D
e
liv
e
re
d
b
y
P
u
b
lis
h
in
g
T
e
ch
n
o
lo
g
y
Io
w
a
S
ta
te
U
n
iv
e
rs
ity
1
2
9
.1
8
6
.1
.5
5
T
u
e
,
0
9
S
e
p
2
0
1
4
1
4
:3
5
:2
5
C
o
p
yr
ig
h
t
M
o
h
r
S
ie
b
e
ck
The Effect of Contract Regulation on Franchising(2012) 49
5 Problems of Inference
Drawing inferences about a single law change is complicated
for both intuitive and
more technical reasons. One intuitive concern involves the
choice of counterfactuals
against which to judge the effect of the Iowa law. In a sense, the
preceding analysis
compares the experience of Iowa to the pooled experience of the
rest of the U.S.
This may be problematic in that Iowa might simply have been
following regional
trends that are obscured when compared to the rest of the
country.
To mitigate this concern, we performed the same analysis
restricting attention to
the Midwestern states in Table 8. For brevity, we present only
the log specifications.
Table 8
Effect of 1992 Iowa Termination Restriction on Franchised
Restaurants: Midwest
Burger King Domino’s Pizza
ln(franchise ln(franchise ln(franchise ln(franchise
units) units) units) units)
Termination −0.12 −0.17 −0.24 −0.80
restriction (0.05)∗ (0.04)∗ ∗ ∗ (0.05)∗ ∗ ∗ (0.05)∗ ∗ ∗
State effects yes yes yes yes
Year effects yes yes yes yes
State trends no yes no yes
Notes: ∗ ∗ ∗ p < 0.01 (against two-sided test of zero effect);
∗ ∗ p < 0.05 (against two-sided
test of zero effect); ∗ p < 0.10 (against two-sided test of zero
effect); standard errors in
parentheses clustered at state level. Sample includes the 12
Midwestern states for the period
1990–2000 (n = 132) for Burger King and 1989–2000 for
Domino’s Pizza (n = 144). Re-
gressions control for constant state per capita income. Franchise
data come from UFOC’s
(item 20) filed with Maryland State Attorney General’s Office.
Examining just the Midwest, we find no evidence that the
earlier analysis was
misleading. In this restricted sample, we find uniformly
negative effects of the Iowa
law, and the magnitude of the effect is comparable to that found
earlier. Also,
despite the large decline in sample size, we continue to find
statistically significant
effects.
Another worry that arises is one of dependence. Applied
empirical economists
have recognized the concerns about dependence at least since
Bertrand, Duflo,
and Mullainathan (2004) which suggested clustering standard
errors at the state
level in policy analyses such as this one. The concern there is
that many eco-
nomic series exhibit serial correlation and laws themselves are
sticky rather than
randomly implemented or repealed each period. In such
applications, standard
errors can be severely understated when there is positive
dependence (or over-
stated when there is negative dependence). Clustering accounts
for this depen-
dence in certain circumstances by inflating or deflating the
standard error estimates
accordingly.
D
e
liv
e
re
d
b
y
P
u
b
lis
h
in
g
T
e
ch
n
o
lo
g
y
Io
w
a
S
ta
te
U
n
iv
e
rs
ity
1
2
9
.1
8
6
.1
.5
5
T
u
e
,
0
9
S
e
p
2
0
1
4
1
4
:3
5
:2
5
C
o
p
yr
ig
h
t
M
o
h
r
S
ie
b
e
ck
J. Klick, B. H. Kobayashi, and L. E. Ribstein50 JITE 168
Rather less attention has been paid to within period dependence.
That is, in the
current context, if Burger King has some national strategy that
affects its activities
in all states but is not sufficiently accounted for by the control
variables (specifically
the year-fixed effects) state observations within a given year
will not be conditionally
independent. This could lead to problems of inference due to
incorrectly calculated
standard errors. Cameron, Gelbach, and Miller (2011) provide a
procedure to ac-
count for this multi-way clustering. We present our estimates
with these standard
errors in Table 9.
Table 9
Effect of 1992 Iowa Termination Restriction on Franchised
Restaurants:
Inference Concerns
Burger King Domino’s Pizza
ln(franchise ln(franchise ln(franchise ln(franchise
units) units) units) units)
Termination −0.06 −0.06 −0.40 −0.40
restriction (0.04) (0.04) (0.04)∗ ∗ ∗ (0.10)∗ ∗ ∗
State effects yes yes yes yes
Year effects yes yes yes yes
State trends no no no no
Clustering state multi-way state multi-way
(state and year) (state and year)
Notes: ∗ ∗ ∗ p < 0.01 (against two-sided test of zero effect);
∗ ∗ p < 0.05 (against two-sided
test of zero effect); ∗ p < 0.10 (against two-sided test of zero
effect). Sample includes the 50
states for the period 1990–2000 (n = 550) for Burger King and
1989–2000 for Domino’s
Pizza (n = 600). Regressions control for constant state per
capita income. Franchise data
come from UFOC’s (item 20) filed with Maryland State
Attorney General’s Office.
We see that while the more sophisticated approach changes
little with respect
to Burger King, the Domino’s coefficient’s standard error
increases by more than
a factor of two. Despite this, however, the effect is still
statistically significant.
A potentially larger problem involves statistical issues having
to do with the very
basis of statistical inference. The standard method of inference
relies on asymptotic
assumptions that may not be justified in small samples. Of
particular concern here
is the fact that our estimate of interest comes from a single law
change. A single
law change may not be sufficient to satisfy the assumptions
supporting a central
limit theorem justification for inference using the standard
approach. If that is the
case, inference in the standard way will only be valid if
normality applies. This is
obviously a very restrictive assumption.
Recent work by Conley and Taber (2011) and Gelbach, Helland,
and Klick (2011)
investigates this problem of inference based on a small number
of policy changes.
The presentations and suggested approaches are quite similar.
Both rely on the fact
that, under the null hypothesis of a zero effect, the residuals for
the non-treatment
observations provide a statistically valid empirical distribution
of the treatment
D
e
liv
e
re
d
b
y
P
u
b
lis
h
in
g
T
e
ch
n
o
lo
g
y
Io
w
a
S
ta
te
U
n
iv
e
rs
ity
1
2
9
.1
8
6
.1
.5
5
T
u
e
,
0
9
S
e
p
2
0
1
4
1
4
:3
5
:2
5
C
o
p
yr
ig
h
t
M
o
h
r
S
ie
b
e
ck
The Effect of Contract Regulation on Franchising(2012) 51
effect coefficient under the null hypothesis. This empirical
distribution can then be
used to judge statistical significance based on how extreme the
estimated treatment
effect is relative to the residuals of the control observations.
The SQ test of Gelbach, Helland, and Klick (2011), which they
develop in the
event study framework, simply compares the point estimate of
the event effect to
the distribution of residuals for non-event observations. In the
current context, we
compared the immediate effect of the Iowa law (i.e., the
estimated law coefficient
restricting attention to 1992 and before) to the residuals from
the model for all non-
Iowa observations. Using a one-tailed test, we found that the
size of the Iowa law
effect on Burger King was more negative than all but the most
extremely negative 2%
of non-Iowa residuals. If, instead, we use a two-tailed test
which simply compares
the magnitude of the effect to the magnitude of the residuals, it
was less extreme
than 12% of the residuals.
For Domino’s, a similar application of the SQ test finds the
effect of the Iowa
law to be more extremely negative than all but 2% of the non-
Iowa residuals, while
a two-tailed test places the Iowa effect as being more extreme,
in absolute value,
than 3% of the non-Iowa residuals.
The Conley and Taber approach, developed in the differences-
in-differences con-
text, estimates the treatment effect and compares it to a placebo
effect occurring at
the same time in each of the non-treatment entities. Using this
approach, Burger
King’s response to the Iowa law was more extremely negative
than 87% of the
observed placebo effects. In absolute value terms, it was more
extreme than 81% of
the placebo effects. For Domino’s, the comparable levels are
99% and 97%. These
results are shown in Table 10.
Table 10
Effect of 1992 Iowa Termination Restriction on Franchised
Restaurants:
Non-Parametric Inference
Burger King Domino’s Pizza
ln(franchise units) ln(franchise units)
Immediate effect of restriction −0.91 −0.49
State effects yes yes
Year effects yes yes
State trends no no
SQ test 1-sided rejects at 2nd percentile rejects at 2nd
percentile
SQ test 2-sided rejects at 12th percentile rejects at 3rd
percentile
C&T test 1-sided rejects at 13th percentile rejects at 1st
percentile
C&T test 2-sided rejects at 19th percentile rejects at 3rd
percentile
Notes: SQ test refers to Gelbach, Helland, and Klick (2010) and
uses the residuals for all
states except Iowa and the District of Columbia for the periods
1990–2000 for Burger King
and 1989–2000 for Domino’s Pizza to construct the empirical
test distribution. C&T refers
to Conley and Taber (2011) and uses the 1992 residual for each
state except Iowa and the
District of Columbia to construct the empirical test distribution.
D
e
liv
e
re
d
b
y
P
u
b
lis
h
in
g
T
e
ch
n
o
lo
g
y
Io
w
a
S
ta
te
U
n
iv
e
rs
ity
1
2
9
.1
8
6
.1
.5
5
T
u
e
,
0
9
S
e
p
2
0
1
4
1
4
:3
5
:2
5
C
o
p
yr
ig
h
t
M
o
h
r
S
ie
b
e
ck
J. Klick, B. H. Kobayashi, and L. E. Ribstein52 JITE 168
While the non-parametric approaches to inference reduce
confidence slightly in
the statistical significance of the effect of the Iowa law on
Burger King, they confirm
the statistical significance of the effect on Domino’s. On the
whole, these results
suggest that the findings are unlikely to be the result of random
variation.
6 Conclusion
While the franchise form has been studied extensively, the
literature exhibits many
limitations. First, the empirical work in this area is almost
exclusively cross-
sectional. This leads to significant problems of causal inference.
Second, economists
have paid too little attention to the legal environment in which
franchise contracts
are interpreted and enforced. This article makes improvements
in both of these areas,
using panel data on the franchise activity of some large fast-
food chains to examine
the effect of laws limiting the use of termination clauses in
franchise contracts.
We also note that these termination laws can vary in their effect
quite a bit from
state to state depending on the degree to which parties can
contract around the
law. We show that there are very different effects of a
termination law in Iowa that
limited contractual avoidance of the law and a similar law in
Washington, D.C. that
did not limit these opportunities. Failure to recognize these
differences limits the
accuracy and the usefulness of previous work in the area. Some
termination laws,
specifically those that limit contractual work arounds,
significantly affect franchise
activity, while those that do not limit avoidance have
ambiguous effects.
References
Bertrand, M., E. Duflo, and S. Mullainathan (2004), “How
Much Should we Trust Differences-
in-Differences Estimates?” The Quarterly Journal of Economics,
119, 249–275.
Brickley, J. (1999), “Incentive Conflicts and Contractual
Restraints: Evidence from Franchis-
ing,” The Journal of Law & Economics, 37, 745–774.
— (2002), “Royalty Rates and Upfront Fees in Share Contracts:
Evidence from Franchising,”
The Journal of Law, Economics, & Organization, 18, 511–535.
—, F. Dark, and M. Weisbach (1991), “The Economic Effects of
Franchise Termination
Laws,” The Journal of Law & Economics, 34, 101–132.
—, S. Misra, and R. Van Horn (2006), “Contract Duration:
Evidence from Franchising,” The
Journal of Law & Economics, 49, 173–196.
Cameron, C., J. Gelbach, and D. Miller (2011), “Robust
Inference with Multi-Way Cluster-
ing,” Journal of Business and Economic Statistics, 29, 238–249.
Coase, R. (1937), “The Nature of the Firm,” Economica, 4, 386–
405.
Conley, T., and C. Taber (2011), “Inference with Difference in
Differences with a Small
Number of Policy Changes,” The Review of Economics and
Statistics, 93, 113–125.
Eisenberg, T. (2012), “Methodological Issues in the Analysis of
Longitudinal Data: Com-
ment,” Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics
(JITE), 168(1), 54–57.
Gelbach, J., E. Helland, and J. Klick (2011), “Valid Inference in
Single Firm, Single-Event
Studies,” Working Paper, available at
http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id
=1442222.
Klein, B. (1995), “The Economics of Franchise Contracts,”
Journal of Corporate Finance, 2,
9–37.
http://www.ingentaconnect.com/content/external-
references?article=0929-1199()2L.9[aid=9284503]
http://www.ingentaconnect.com/content/external-
references?article=0929-1199()2L.9[aid=9284503]
http://www.ingentaconnect.com/content/external-
references?article=0013-0427()4L.386[aid=42424]
http://www.ingentaconnect.com/content/external-
references?article=0735-0015()29L.238[aid=9840269]
http://www.ingentaconnect.com/content/external-
references?article=0022-2186()34L.101[aid=4750675]
http://www.ingentaconnect.com/content/external-
references?article=8756-6222()18L.511[aid=9840271]
http://www.ingentaconnect.com/content/external-
references?article=0033-5533()119L.249[aid=6041958]
http://www.ingentaconnect.com/content/external-
references?article=0932-4569()168L.54[aid=9840273]
http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id
D
e
liv
e
re
d
b
y
P
u
b
lis
h
in
g
T
e
ch
n
o
lo
g
y
Io
w
a
S
ta
te
U
n
iv
e
rs
ity
1
2
9
.1
8
6
.1
.5
5
T
u
e
,
0
9
S
e
p
2
0
1
4
1
4
:3
5
:2
5
C
o
p
yr
ig
h
t
M
o
h
r
S
ie
b
e
ck
The Effect of Contract Regulation on Franchising(2012) 53
Klick, J., B. Kobayashi, and L. Ribstein (2009), “Federalism,
Variation, and State Regulation
of Franchise Termination,” Entrepreneurial Business Law
Journal, 3, 355–379.
Kobayashi, B. H., and L. E. Ribstein (1999), “Contract and
Jurisdictional Freedom,” in: F. H.
Buckley (ed.), The Fall and Rise of Freedom of Contract, Duke
University Press, Durham
(NC), pp. 325–349.
Lafontaine, F., and S. Masten (1995), “Franchise Contracting,
Organization, and Regulation:
Introduction,” Journal of Corporate Finance, 2, 1–7.
Marvel, H. (1995), “Tying, Franchising, and Gasoline Service
Stations,” Journal of Corporate
Finance, 2, 199–225.
Muris, T., and H. Beales (1994), “State Regulation of Franchise
Contracts,” unpublished
Manuscript, George Mason University School of Law, Arlington
(VA) and George Wash-
ington University, Washington, DC.
O’Hara, E. A., and L. E. Ribstein (2009), The Law Market,
Oxford University Press, New
York.
Roider, A. (2012), “The Effect of Contract Regulation on
Franchising: Comment,” Journal
of Institutional and Theoretical Economics (JITE), 168(1), 58–
61.
Rubin, P. (1978), “The Theory of the Firm and the Structure of
the Franchise Contract,” The
Journal of Law & Economics, 21, 223–233.
Smith, R. (1982), “Franchise Regulation: An Economic Analysis
of State Restrictions on
Automobile Distribution,” The Journal of Law & Economics,
25, 125–157.
Jonathan Klick
Law School
University of Pennsylvania
3400 Chestnut Street
Philadelphia, PA 19104
U.S.A.
E-mail:
[email protected]
Bruce H. Kobayashi
School of Law
George Mason University
3301 Fairfax Drive
Arlington, VA 22201
U.S.A.
E-mail:
[email protected]
Larry E. Ribstein
College of Law
University of Illinois
504 E. Pennsylvania Avenue
Champaign, IL 61820
U.S.A.
E-mail:
[email protected]
http://www.ingentaconnect.com/content/external-
references?article=0022-2186()21L.223[aid=223108]
http://www.ingentaconnect.com/content/external-
references?article=0022-2186()21L.223[aid=223108]
http://www.ingentaconnect.com/content/external-
references?article=0929-1199()2L.199[aid=9840275]
http://www.ingentaconnect.com/content/external-
references?article=0929-1199()2L.199[aid=9840275]
http://www.ingentaconnect.com/content/external-
references?article=0929-1199()2L.1[aid=9840276]
http://www.ingentaconnect.com/content/external-
references?article=0932-4569()168L.58[aid=9840278]
http://www.ingentaconnect.com/content/external-
references?article=0932-4569()168L.58[aid=9840278]
Instructions for Academic article critique #2 (please submit to
Turnitin link above)
You are assigned to read and critique the attached papers to be
submitted at the end of week 4 ( Sunday before 11:59 PM).
Academic research may provide helpful insights to
practitioners. As a graduate student, one of the more important
skills you will develop, is the ability to read, understand,
and critique an academic article.
The length of your paper must be a minimum of 50 words for
each section of the 7 sections, listed below.
*Make sure to write down each of the questions in the order
listed below as a heading (Title), followed by your answers
that are specifically related to the question. DO NOT MIX
THEM ALL TOGETHER.
ASSIGNMENT FORMAT: For this assignment you need to
prepare and submit a critique of the attached article in week 4
under the assignment # 2 in ulearn. Your critique must answer
the following questions:
1. What was the intent of this research?
2. How was the research conducted (method)?
3. What was the sample for this research, and how was it
determined?
4. What were the conclusions of the article?
5. Is this research actionable? In other words, could it be put
into use in any practical way in a Franchisee or Franchisor
business?
6. What in this article did you find most important?
7. What in this article did you find least important?
Your paper needs to meet the following formatting
requirements:
*Make sure to write down each of the questions in an order
listed above, followed by your answers that are specifically
related to the question. DO NOT MIX THEM ALL TOGETHER
• Microsoft Word Document
• Margins 1 inch in each side, 1.5 top and bottom.
• Double spaced
• Any citations in text in APA 6th Edition format.
• References at the end of your critique, also in APA 6th
edition format.
• No spelling errors
• No grammatical errors
• A Turnitin Originality Score of 25% or less (in other words,
more than 75% of the paper must be in your own words
• Your Article Critique must be submitted via the Turnitin
link before 11:59PM on Sunday of the week assigned
Delivered by Publishin.docx

More Related Content

Similar to Delivered by Publishin.docx

Mergers Acquisitions and Other Restructuring Activities 9th Edition DePamphil...
Mergers Acquisitions and Other Restructuring Activities 9th Edition DePamphil...Mergers Acquisitions and Other Restructuring Activities 9th Edition DePamphil...
Mergers Acquisitions and Other Restructuring Activities 9th Edition DePamphil...lujepyce
 
The determinants of financial covenants on private debt
The determinants of financial covenants on private debtThe determinants of financial covenants on private debt
The determinants of financial covenants on private debtAlexander Decker
 
10 Small Bus and New Mistakes Article, August 2015, BNA Bloomberg FCR
10 Small Bus and New Mistakes Article, August 2015, BNA Bloomberg FCR10 Small Bus and New Mistakes Article, August 2015, BNA Bloomberg FCR
10 Small Bus and New Mistakes Article, August 2015, BNA Bloomberg FCRRichard D. Lieberman
 
Valuation Insights - Q4 2017
Valuation Insights - Q4 2017Valuation Insights - Q4 2017
Valuation Insights - Q4 2017Duff & Phelps
 
Valuation Discounts Gone? Don't Lose Hope
Valuation Discounts Gone? Don't Lose HopeValuation Discounts Gone? Don't Lose Hope
Valuation Discounts Gone? Don't Lose HopetheBurgessGroup
 
A PRACTICAL GUIDE TO ORGANIZATIONAL CONFLICT OF INTEREST FAR SUBPART 9.5
A PRACTICAL GUIDE TO ORGANIZATIONAL CONFLICT OF INTEREST FAR SUBPART 9.5 A PRACTICAL GUIDE TO ORGANIZATIONAL CONFLICT OF INTEREST FAR SUBPART 9.5
A PRACTICAL GUIDE TO ORGANIZATIONAL CONFLICT OF INTEREST FAR SUBPART 9.5 dbolton007
 
Minimizing Risks and Maximizing Success in Government Contracting
Minimizing Risks and Maximizing Success in Government ContractingMinimizing Risks and Maximizing Success in Government Contracting
Minimizing Risks and Maximizing Success in Government Contractinglruzicka
 
Why Canada's "Costly" Securities Regulation Regime Ensures Better Decision-ma...
Why Canada's "Costly" Securities Regulation Regime Ensures Better Decision-ma...Why Canada's "Costly" Securities Regulation Regime Ensures Better Decision-ma...
Why Canada's "Costly" Securities Regulation Regime Ensures Better Decision-ma...EzraS
 
Afri cog comments on the capital markets authority regulation
Afri cog comments on the capital markets authority regulationAfri cog comments on the capital markets authority regulation
Afri cog comments on the capital markets authority regulationAfrica Centre For Open Governance
 
Attacking Tax Shelters Galloping Toward A Better Step TransactionDoctrine
Attacking Tax Shelters  Galloping Toward A Better Step TransactionDoctrineAttacking Tax Shelters  Galloping Toward A Better Step TransactionDoctrine
Attacking Tax Shelters Galloping Toward A Better Step TransactionDoctrineDon Dooley
 
ARTICLE IN PRESSJournal of Accounting and Economics 44 (2007.docx
ARTICLE IN PRESSJournal of Accounting and Economics 44 (2007.docxARTICLE IN PRESSJournal of Accounting and Economics 44 (2007.docx
ARTICLE IN PRESSJournal of Accounting and Economics 44 (2007.docxfredharris32
 
August 2012 Just Out Of Reish Plan Sponsor
August 2012 Just Out Of Reish Plan SponsorAugust 2012 Just Out Of Reish Plan Sponsor
August 2012 Just Out Of Reish Plan Sponsorfredreish
 
Agency Design and Policy-Based Evidence-Making at the Consumer Financial Prot...
Agency Design and Policy-Based Evidence-Making at the Consumer Financial Prot...Agency Design and Policy-Based Evidence-Making at the Consumer Financial Prot...
Agency Design and Policy-Based Evidence-Making at the Consumer Financial Prot...Mercatus Center
 
The Taylor Law (particularly the Triborough Amendment provision) expires on J...
The Taylor Law (particularly the Triborough Amendment provision) expires on J...The Taylor Law (particularly the Triborough Amendment provision) expires on J...
The Taylor Law (particularly the Triborough Amendment provision) expires on J...Luis Taveras EMBA, MS
 
LA Lawyer Article Dec 2016 - Hiraide
LA Lawyer Article Dec 2016 - HiraideLA Lawyer Article Dec 2016 - Hiraide
LA Lawyer Article Dec 2016 - HiraideMark Hiraide
 
Gabriel Hernandez_Assignment 2b_BUL 6890
Gabriel Hernandez_Assignment 2b_BUL 6890Gabriel Hernandez_Assignment 2b_BUL 6890
Gabriel Hernandez_Assignment 2b_BUL 6890Gabriel Hernandez Fonte
 
NAMICCongressionalTestimony2003
NAMICCongressionalTestimony2003NAMICCongressionalTestimony2003
NAMICCongressionalTestimony2003Roger Schmelzer
 

Similar to Delivered by Publishin.docx (20)

Mergers Acquisitions and Other Restructuring Activities 9th Edition DePamphil...
Mergers Acquisitions and Other Restructuring Activities 9th Edition DePamphil...Mergers Acquisitions and Other Restructuring Activities 9th Edition DePamphil...
Mergers Acquisitions and Other Restructuring Activities 9th Edition DePamphil...
 
The determinants of financial covenants on private debt
The determinants of financial covenants on private debtThe determinants of financial covenants on private debt
The determinants of financial covenants on private debt
 
10 Small Bus and New Mistakes Article, August 2015, BNA Bloomberg FCR
10 Small Bus and New Mistakes Article, August 2015, BNA Bloomberg FCR10 Small Bus and New Mistakes Article, August 2015, BNA Bloomberg FCR
10 Small Bus and New Mistakes Article, August 2015, BNA Bloomberg FCR
 
Valuation Insights - Q4 2017
Valuation Insights - Q4 2017Valuation Insights - Q4 2017
Valuation Insights - Q4 2017
 
Valuation Discounts Gone? Don't Lose Hope
Valuation Discounts Gone? Don't Lose HopeValuation Discounts Gone? Don't Lose Hope
Valuation Discounts Gone? Don't Lose Hope
 
A PRACTICAL GUIDE TO ORGANIZATIONAL CONFLICT OF INTEREST FAR SUBPART 9.5
A PRACTICAL GUIDE TO ORGANIZATIONAL CONFLICT OF INTEREST FAR SUBPART 9.5 A PRACTICAL GUIDE TO ORGANIZATIONAL CONFLICT OF INTEREST FAR SUBPART 9.5
A PRACTICAL GUIDE TO ORGANIZATIONAL CONFLICT OF INTEREST FAR SUBPART 9.5
 
Minimizing Risks and Maximizing Success in Government Contracting
Minimizing Risks and Maximizing Success in Government ContractingMinimizing Risks and Maximizing Success in Government Contracting
Minimizing Risks and Maximizing Success in Government Contracting
 
An Empirical Study: Financial-Market Imperfections and Investment
An Empirical Study: Financial-Market Imperfections and InvestmentAn Empirical Study: Financial-Market Imperfections and Investment
An Empirical Study: Financial-Market Imperfections and Investment
 
Why Canada's "Costly" Securities Regulation Regime Ensures Better Decision-ma...
Why Canada's "Costly" Securities Regulation Regime Ensures Better Decision-ma...Why Canada's "Costly" Securities Regulation Regime Ensures Better Decision-ma...
Why Canada's "Costly" Securities Regulation Regime Ensures Better Decision-ma...
 
Afri cog comments on the capital markets authority regulation
Afri cog comments on the capital markets authority regulationAfri cog comments on the capital markets authority regulation
Afri cog comments on the capital markets authority regulation
 
Attacking Tax Shelters Galloping Toward A Better Step TransactionDoctrine
Attacking Tax Shelters  Galloping Toward A Better Step TransactionDoctrineAttacking Tax Shelters  Galloping Toward A Better Step TransactionDoctrine
Attacking Tax Shelters Galloping Toward A Better Step TransactionDoctrine
 
ARTICLE IN PRESSJournal of Accounting and Economics 44 (2007.docx
ARTICLE IN PRESSJournal of Accounting and Economics 44 (2007.docxARTICLE IN PRESSJournal of Accounting and Economics 44 (2007.docx
ARTICLE IN PRESSJournal of Accounting and Economics 44 (2007.docx
 
401k Whitepaper
401k Whitepaper401k Whitepaper
401k Whitepaper
 
August 2012 Just Out Of Reish Plan Sponsor
August 2012 Just Out Of Reish Plan SponsorAugust 2012 Just Out Of Reish Plan Sponsor
August 2012 Just Out Of Reish Plan Sponsor
 
Agency Design and Policy-Based Evidence-Making at the Consumer Financial Prot...
Agency Design and Policy-Based Evidence-Making at the Consumer Financial Prot...Agency Design and Policy-Based Evidence-Making at the Consumer Financial Prot...
Agency Design and Policy-Based Evidence-Making at the Consumer Financial Prot...
 
The Taylor Law (particularly the Triborough Amendment provision) expires on J...
The Taylor Law (particularly the Triborough Amendment provision) expires on J...The Taylor Law (particularly the Triborough Amendment provision) expires on J...
The Taylor Law (particularly the Triborough Amendment provision) expires on J...
 
LA Lawyer Article Dec 2016 - Hiraide
LA Lawyer Article Dec 2016 - HiraideLA Lawyer Article Dec 2016 - Hiraide
LA Lawyer Article Dec 2016 - Hiraide
 
Gabriel Hernandez_Assignment 2b_BUL 6890
Gabriel Hernandez_Assignment 2b_BUL 6890Gabriel Hernandez_Assignment 2b_BUL 6890
Gabriel Hernandez_Assignment 2b_BUL 6890
 
Orden sin ley
Orden sin leyOrden sin ley
Orden sin ley
 
NAMICCongressionalTestimony2003
NAMICCongressionalTestimony2003NAMICCongressionalTestimony2003
NAMICCongressionalTestimony2003
 

More from cargillfilberto

COMMONALITY AND DIVERSITY OF OPERATING SYSTEMS .docx
COMMONALITY AND DIVERSITY OF OPERATING SYSTEMS                .docxCOMMONALITY AND DIVERSITY OF OPERATING SYSTEMS                .docx
COMMONALITY AND DIVERSITY OF OPERATING SYSTEMS .docxcargillfilberto
 
Common Mistakes I see on this paper are1. Using summaries and .docx
Common Mistakes I see on this paper are1. Using summaries and .docxCommon Mistakes I see on this paper are1. Using summaries and .docx
Common Mistakes I see on this paper are1. Using summaries and .docxcargillfilberto
 
Common symptoms of memory changes during the lifetime in healthy.docx
Common symptoms of memory changes during the lifetime in healthy.docxCommon symptoms of memory changes during the lifetime in healthy.docx
Common symptoms of memory changes during the lifetime in healthy.docxcargillfilberto
 
Common Surface-Level Issues for the Informative Essay(Note Thes.docx
Common Surface-Level Issues for the Informative Essay(Note Thes.docxCommon Surface-Level Issues for the Informative Essay(Note Thes.docx
Common Surface-Level Issues for the Informative Essay(Note Thes.docxcargillfilberto
 
Commercial Space TravelThere are about a half dozen commercial s.docx
Commercial Space TravelThere are about a half dozen commercial s.docxCommercial Space TravelThere are about a half dozen commercial s.docx
Commercial Space TravelThere are about a half dozen commercial s.docxcargillfilberto
 
Common sports-relatedshoulder injuriesShoulder pain is.docx
Common sports-relatedshoulder injuriesShoulder pain is.docxCommon sports-relatedshoulder injuriesShoulder pain is.docx
Common sports-relatedshoulder injuriesShoulder pain is.docxcargillfilberto
 
Common Product Yields VEGETABLES Acorn Squash.docx
Common Product Yields  VEGETABLES Acorn Squash.docxCommon Product Yields  VEGETABLES Acorn Squash.docx
Common Product Yields VEGETABLES Acorn Squash.docxcargillfilberto
 
Common Law Strict Liability Introduction Strict liabilit.docx
Common Law Strict Liability Introduction  Strict liabilit.docxCommon Law Strict Liability Introduction  Strict liabilit.docx
Common Law Strict Liability Introduction Strict liabilit.docxcargillfilberto
 
common core state stanDarDs For english Language arts & .docx
common core state stanDarDs For english Language arts & .docxcommon core state stanDarDs For english Language arts & .docx
common core state stanDarDs For english Language arts & .docxcargillfilberto
 
COMMON ETHICAL PROBLEMS OF INDIVIDUALSBA 354COLLEG.docx
COMMON ETHICAL PROBLEMS OF INDIVIDUALSBA 354COLLEG.docxCOMMON ETHICAL PROBLEMS OF INDIVIDUALSBA 354COLLEG.docx
COMMON ETHICAL PROBLEMS OF INDIVIDUALSBA 354COLLEG.docxcargillfilberto
 
Common CoreCasey BerryEnglish 200August .docx
Common CoreCasey BerryEnglish  200August .docxCommon CoreCasey BerryEnglish  200August .docx
Common CoreCasey BerryEnglish 200August .docxcargillfilberto
 
Common Holy Days in Jewish Religious TraditionsComplete th.docx
Common Holy Days in Jewish Religious TraditionsComplete th.docxCommon Holy Days in Jewish Religious TraditionsComplete th.docx
Common Holy Days in Jewish Religious TraditionsComplete th.docxcargillfilberto
 
Common Hacking Techniques You Should Know AboutHacking is th.docx
Common Hacking Techniques You Should Know AboutHacking is th.docxCommon Hacking Techniques You Should Know AboutHacking is th.docx
Common Hacking Techniques You Should Know AboutHacking is th.docxcargillfilberto
 
Common Pool Resource ManagementKim Townsend SUS 350 Sustai.docx
Common Pool Resource ManagementKim Townsend SUS 350 Sustai.docxCommon Pool Resource ManagementKim Townsend SUS 350 Sustai.docx
Common Pool Resource ManagementKim Townsend SUS 350 Sustai.docxcargillfilberto
 
Common Assignment Prepare a written analysis of the impact of the.docx
Common Assignment Prepare a written analysis of the impact of the.docxCommon Assignment Prepare a written analysis of the impact of the.docx
Common Assignment Prepare a written analysis of the impact of the.docxcargillfilberto
 
Common Assignment Essay Objective of this Assignment.docx
Common Assignment Essay   Objective of this Assignment.docxCommon Assignment Essay   Objective of this Assignment.docx
Common Assignment Essay Objective of this Assignment.docxcargillfilberto
 
Committee on Enhancing Federal Healthcare Quality ProgramsJa.docx
Committee on Enhancing Federal Healthcare Quality ProgramsJa.docxCommittee on Enhancing Federal Healthcare Quality ProgramsJa.docx
Committee on Enhancing Federal Healthcare Quality ProgramsJa.docxcargillfilberto
 
Committees1. To provide for greater transparency in the HU.docx
Committees1. To provide for greater transparency in the HU.docxCommittees1. To provide for greater transparency in the HU.docx
Committees1. To provide for greater transparency in the HU.docxcargillfilberto
 
Commitment to ProfessionalismCommitment to Professionalism..docx
Commitment to ProfessionalismCommitment to Professionalism..docxCommitment to ProfessionalismCommitment to Professionalism..docx
Commitment to ProfessionalismCommitment to Professionalism..docxcargillfilberto
 

More from cargillfilberto (20)

COMMONALITY AND DIVERSITY OF OPERATING SYSTEMS .docx
COMMONALITY AND DIVERSITY OF OPERATING SYSTEMS                .docxCOMMONALITY AND DIVERSITY OF OPERATING SYSTEMS                .docx
COMMONALITY AND DIVERSITY OF OPERATING SYSTEMS .docx
 
Common Mistakes I see on this paper are1. Using summaries and .docx
Common Mistakes I see on this paper are1. Using summaries and .docxCommon Mistakes I see on this paper are1. Using summaries and .docx
Common Mistakes I see on this paper are1. Using summaries and .docx
 
Common symptoms of memory changes during the lifetime in healthy.docx
Common symptoms of memory changes during the lifetime in healthy.docxCommon symptoms of memory changes during the lifetime in healthy.docx
Common symptoms of memory changes during the lifetime in healthy.docx
 
Common Surface-Level Issues for the Informative Essay(Note Thes.docx
Common Surface-Level Issues for the Informative Essay(Note Thes.docxCommon Surface-Level Issues for the Informative Essay(Note Thes.docx
Common Surface-Level Issues for the Informative Essay(Note Thes.docx
 
Commercial Space TravelThere are about a half dozen commercial s.docx
Commercial Space TravelThere are about a half dozen commercial s.docxCommercial Space TravelThere are about a half dozen commercial s.docx
Commercial Space TravelThere are about a half dozen commercial s.docx
 
Common sports-relatedshoulder injuriesShoulder pain is.docx
Common sports-relatedshoulder injuriesShoulder pain is.docxCommon sports-relatedshoulder injuriesShoulder pain is.docx
Common sports-relatedshoulder injuriesShoulder pain is.docx
 
Common Product Yields VEGETABLES Acorn Squash.docx
Common Product Yields  VEGETABLES Acorn Squash.docxCommon Product Yields  VEGETABLES Acorn Squash.docx
Common Product Yields VEGETABLES Acorn Squash.docx
 
Common Law Strict Liability Introduction Strict liabilit.docx
Common Law Strict Liability Introduction  Strict liabilit.docxCommon Law Strict Liability Introduction  Strict liabilit.docx
Common Law Strict Liability Introduction Strict liabilit.docx
 
Common Core .docx
Common Core                                                       .docxCommon Core                                                       .docx
Common Core .docx
 
common core state stanDarDs For english Language arts & .docx
common core state stanDarDs For english Language arts & .docxcommon core state stanDarDs For english Language arts & .docx
common core state stanDarDs For english Language arts & .docx
 
COMMON ETHICAL PROBLEMS OF INDIVIDUALSBA 354COLLEG.docx
COMMON ETHICAL PROBLEMS OF INDIVIDUALSBA 354COLLEG.docxCOMMON ETHICAL PROBLEMS OF INDIVIDUALSBA 354COLLEG.docx
COMMON ETHICAL PROBLEMS OF INDIVIDUALSBA 354COLLEG.docx
 
Common CoreCasey BerryEnglish 200August .docx
Common CoreCasey BerryEnglish  200August .docxCommon CoreCasey BerryEnglish  200August .docx
Common CoreCasey BerryEnglish 200August .docx
 
Common Holy Days in Jewish Religious TraditionsComplete th.docx
Common Holy Days in Jewish Religious TraditionsComplete th.docxCommon Holy Days in Jewish Religious TraditionsComplete th.docx
Common Holy Days in Jewish Religious TraditionsComplete th.docx
 
Common Hacking Techniques You Should Know AboutHacking is th.docx
Common Hacking Techniques You Should Know AboutHacking is th.docxCommon Hacking Techniques You Should Know AboutHacking is th.docx
Common Hacking Techniques You Should Know AboutHacking is th.docx
 
Common Pool Resource ManagementKim Townsend SUS 350 Sustai.docx
Common Pool Resource ManagementKim Townsend SUS 350 Sustai.docxCommon Pool Resource ManagementKim Townsend SUS 350 Sustai.docx
Common Pool Resource ManagementKim Townsend SUS 350 Sustai.docx
 
Common Assignment Prepare a written analysis of the impact of the.docx
Common Assignment Prepare a written analysis of the impact of the.docxCommon Assignment Prepare a written analysis of the impact of the.docx
Common Assignment Prepare a written analysis of the impact of the.docx
 
Common Assignment Essay Objective of this Assignment.docx
Common Assignment Essay   Objective of this Assignment.docxCommon Assignment Essay   Objective of this Assignment.docx
Common Assignment Essay Objective of this Assignment.docx
 
Committee on Enhancing Federal Healthcare Quality ProgramsJa.docx
Committee on Enhancing Federal Healthcare Quality ProgramsJa.docxCommittee on Enhancing Federal Healthcare Quality ProgramsJa.docx
Committee on Enhancing Federal Healthcare Quality ProgramsJa.docx
 
Committees1. To provide for greater transparency in the HU.docx
Committees1. To provide for greater transparency in the HU.docxCommittees1. To provide for greater transparency in the HU.docx
Committees1. To provide for greater transparency in the HU.docx
 
Commitment to ProfessionalismCommitment to Professionalism..docx
Commitment to ProfessionalismCommitment to Professionalism..docxCommitment to ProfessionalismCommitment to Professionalism..docx
Commitment to ProfessionalismCommitment to Professionalism..docx
 

Recently uploaded

microwave assisted reaction. General introduction
microwave assisted reaction. General introductionmicrowave assisted reaction. General introduction
microwave assisted reaction. General introductionMaksud Ahmed
 
Incoming and Outgoing Shipments in 1 STEP Using Odoo 17
Incoming and Outgoing Shipments in 1 STEP Using Odoo 17Incoming and Outgoing Shipments in 1 STEP Using Odoo 17
Incoming and Outgoing Shipments in 1 STEP Using Odoo 17Celine George
 
Enzyme, Pharmaceutical Aids, Miscellaneous Last Part of Chapter no 5th.pdf
Enzyme, Pharmaceutical Aids, Miscellaneous Last Part of Chapter no 5th.pdfEnzyme, Pharmaceutical Aids, Miscellaneous Last Part of Chapter no 5th.pdf
Enzyme, Pharmaceutical Aids, Miscellaneous Last Part of Chapter no 5th.pdfSumit Tiwari
 
Introduction to ArtificiaI Intelligence in Higher Education
Introduction to ArtificiaI Intelligence in Higher EducationIntroduction to ArtificiaI Intelligence in Higher Education
Introduction to ArtificiaI Intelligence in Higher Educationpboyjonauth
 
Call Girls in Dwarka Mor Delhi Contact Us 9654467111
Call Girls in Dwarka Mor Delhi Contact Us 9654467111Call Girls in Dwarka Mor Delhi Contact Us 9654467111
Call Girls in Dwarka Mor Delhi Contact Us 9654467111Sapana Sha
 
Software Engineering Methodologies (overview)
Software Engineering Methodologies (overview)Software Engineering Methodologies (overview)
Software Engineering Methodologies (overview)eniolaolutunde
 
Separation of Lanthanides/ Lanthanides and Actinides
Separation of Lanthanides/ Lanthanides and ActinidesSeparation of Lanthanides/ Lanthanides and Actinides
Separation of Lanthanides/ Lanthanides and ActinidesFatimaKhan178732
 
Contemporary philippine arts from the regions_PPT_Module_12 [Autosaved] (1).pptx
Contemporary philippine arts from the regions_PPT_Module_12 [Autosaved] (1).pptxContemporary philippine arts from the regions_PPT_Module_12 [Autosaved] (1).pptx
Contemporary philippine arts from the regions_PPT_Module_12 [Autosaved] (1).pptxRoyAbrique
 
Crayon Activity Handout For the Crayon A
Crayon Activity Handout For the Crayon ACrayon Activity Handout For the Crayon A
Crayon Activity Handout For the Crayon AUnboundStockton
 
ECONOMIC CONTEXT - LONG FORM TV DRAMA - PPT
ECONOMIC CONTEXT - LONG FORM TV DRAMA - PPTECONOMIC CONTEXT - LONG FORM TV DRAMA - PPT
ECONOMIC CONTEXT - LONG FORM TV DRAMA - PPTiammrhaywood
 
Hybridoma Technology ( Production , Purification , and Application )
Hybridoma Technology  ( Production , Purification , and Application  ) Hybridoma Technology  ( Production , Purification , and Application  )
Hybridoma Technology ( Production , Purification , and Application ) Sakshi Ghasle
 
MENTAL STATUS EXAMINATION format.docx
MENTAL     STATUS EXAMINATION format.docxMENTAL     STATUS EXAMINATION format.docx
MENTAL STATUS EXAMINATION format.docxPoojaSen20
 
BASLIQ CURRENT LOOKBOOK LOOKBOOK(1) (1).pdf
BASLIQ CURRENT LOOKBOOK  LOOKBOOK(1) (1).pdfBASLIQ CURRENT LOOKBOOK  LOOKBOOK(1) (1).pdf
BASLIQ CURRENT LOOKBOOK LOOKBOOK(1) (1).pdfSoniaTolstoy
 
How to Make a Pirate ship Primary Education.pptx
How to Make a Pirate ship Primary Education.pptxHow to Make a Pirate ship Primary Education.pptx
How to Make a Pirate ship Primary Education.pptxmanuelaromero2013
 
Presiding Officer Training module 2024 lok sabha elections
Presiding Officer Training module 2024 lok sabha electionsPresiding Officer Training module 2024 lok sabha elections
Presiding Officer Training module 2024 lok sabha electionsanshu789521
 
Kisan Call Centre - To harness potential of ICT in Agriculture by answer farm...
Kisan Call Centre - To harness potential of ICT in Agriculture by answer farm...Kisan Call Centre - To harness potential of ICT in Agriculture by answer farm...
Kisan Call Centre - To harness potential of ICT in Agriculture by answer farm...Krashi Coaching
 
call girls in Kamla Market (DELHI) 🔝 >༒9953330565🔝 genuine Escort Service 🔝✔️✔️
call girls in Kamla Market (DELHI) 🔝 >༒9953330565🔝 genuine Escort Service 🔝✔️✔️call girls in Kamla Market (DELHI) 🔝 >༒9953330565🔝 genuine Escort Service 🔝✔️✔️
call girls in Kamla Market (DELHI) 🔝 >༒9953330565🔝 genuine Escort Service 🔝✔️✔️9953056974 Low Rate Call Girls In Saket, Delhi NCR
 

Recently uploaded (20)

microwave assisted reaction. General introduction
microwave assisted reaction. General introductionmicrowave assisted reaction. General introduction
microwave assisted reaction. General introduction
 
Incoming and Outgoing Shipments in 1 STEP Using Odoo 17
Incoming and Outgoing Shipments in 1 STEP Using Odoo 17Incoming and Outgoing Shipments in 1 STEP Using Odoo 17
Incoming and Outgoing Shipments in 1 STEP Using Odoo 17
 
Enzyme, Pharmaceutical Aids, Miscellaneous Last Part of Chapter no 5th.pdf
Enzyme, Pharmaceutical Aids, Miscellaneous Last Part of Chapter no 5th.pdfEnzyme, Pharmaceutical Aids, Miscellaneous Last Part of Chapter no 5th.pdf
Enzyme, Pharmaceutical Aids, Miscellaneous Last Part of Chapter no 5th.pdf
 
Introduction to ArtificiaI Intelligence in Higher Education
Introduction to ArtificiaI Intelligence in Higher EducationIntroduction to ArtificiaI Intelligence in Higher Education
Introduction to ArtificiaI Intelligence in Higher Education
 
Staff of Color (SOC) Retention Efforts DDSD
Staff of Color (SOC) Retention Efforts DDSDStaff of Color (SOC) Retention Efforts DDSD
Staff of Color (SOC) Retention Efforts DDSD
 
Call Girls in Dwarka Mor Delhi Contact Us 9654467111
Call Girls in Dwarka Mor Delhi Contact Us 9654467111Call Girls in Dwarka Mor Delhi Contact Us 9654467111
Call Girls in Dwarka Mor Delhi Contact Us 9654467111
 
Model Call Girl in Tilak Nagar Delhi reach out to us at 🔝9953056974🔝
Model Call Girl in Tilak Nagar Delhi reach out to us at 🔝9953056974🔝Model Call Girl in Tilak Nagar Delhi reach out to us at 🔝9953056974🔝
Model Call Girl in Tilak Nagar Delhi reach out to us at 🔝9953056974🔝
 
Software Engineering Methodologies (overview)
Software Engineering Methodologies (overview)Software Engineering Methodologies (overview)
Software Engineering Methodologies (overview)
 
Código Creativo y Arte de Software | Unidad 1
Código Creativo y Arte de Software | Unidad 1Código Creativo y Arte de Software | Unidad 1
Código Creativo y Arte de Software | Unidad 1
 
Separation of Lanthanides/ Lanthanides and Actinides
Separation of Lanthanides/ Lanthanides and ActinidesSeparation of Lanthanides/ Lanthanides and Actinides
Separation of Lanthanides/ Lanthanides and Actinides
 
Contemporary philippine arts from the regions_PPT_Module_12 [Autosaved] (1).pptx
Contemporary philippine arts from the regions_PPT_Module_12 [Autosaved] (1).pptxContemporary philippine arts from the regions_PPT_Module_12 [Autosaved] (1).pptx
Contemporary philippine arts from the regions_PPT_Module_12 [Autosaved] (1).pptx
 
Crayon Activity Handout For the Crayon A
Crayon Activity Handout For the Crayon ACrayon Activity Handout For the Crayon A
Crayon Activity Handout For the Crayon A
 
ECONOMIC CONTEXT - LONG FORM TV DRAMA - PPT
ECONOMIC CONTEXT - LONG FORM TV DRAMA - PPTECONOMIC CONTEXT - LONG FORM TV DRAMA - PPT
ECONOMIC CONTEXT - LONG FORM TV DRAMA - PPT
 
Hybridoma Technology ( Production , Purification , and Application )
Hybridoma Technology  ( Production , Purification , and Application  ) Hybridoma Technology  ( Production , Purification , and Application  )
Hybridoma Technology ( Production , Purification , and Application )
 
MENTAL STATUS EXAMINATION format.docx
MENTAL     STATUS EXAMINATION format.docxMENTAL     STATUS EXAMINATION format.docx
MENTAL STATUS EXAMINATION format.docx
 
BASLIQ CURRENT LOOKBOOK LOOKBOOK(1) (1).pdf
BASLIQ CURRENT LOOKBOOK  LOOKBOOK(1) (1).pdfBASLIQ CURRENT LOOKBOOK  LOOKBOOK(1) (1).pdf
BASLIQ CURRENT LOOKBOOK LOOKBOOK(1) (1).pdf
 
How to Make a Pirate ship Primary Education.pptx
How to Make a Pirate ship Primary Education.pptxHow to Make a Pirate ship Primary Education.pptx
How to Make a Pirate ship Primary Education.pptx
 
Presiding Officer Training module 2024 lok sabha elections
Presiding Officer Training module 2024 lok sabha electionsPresiding Officer Training module 2024 lok sabha elections
Presiding Officer Training module 2024 lok sabha elections
 
Kisan Call Centre - To harness potential of ICT in Agriculture by answer farm...
Kisan Call Centre - To harness potential of ICT in Agriculture by answer farm...Kisan Call Centre - To harness potential of ICT in Agriculture by answer farm...
Kisan Call Centre - To harness potential of ICT in Agriculture by answer farm...
 
call girls in Kamla Market (DELHI) 🔝 >༒9953330565🔝 genuine Escort Service 🔝✔️✔️
call girls in Kamla Market (DELHI) 🔝 >༒9953330565🔝 genuine Escort Service 🔝✔️✔️call girls in Kamla Market (DELHI) 🔝 >༒9953330565🔝 genuine Escort Service 🔝✔️✔️
call girls in Kamla Market (DELHI) 🔝 >༒9953330565🔝 genuine Escort Service 🔝✔️✔️
 

Delivered by Publishin.docx

  • 4. b e ck 38 The Effect of Contract Regulation on Franchising by Jonathan Klick, Bruce H. Kobayashi, and Larry E. Ribstein∗ Previous work on the regulation of termination clauses in franchise contracts has ignored the ability of parties to contract around state law. Using data on two na- tional fast-food restaurants, we find that Washington, D.C.’s termination restric- tion which did not restrict choice-of-law provisions had little systematic effect on business practice, while Iowa’s termination restriction which did prohibit choice- of-law provisions had a large negative effect on franchising. (JEL: D86, K12, K20, L14) 1 Introduction Franchising is an important and frequently studied form of organization. Prior articles have used the franchising form to examine the general nature of intra- versus interfirm contracting1 and to analyze how contracts and incentives are used to reduce transaction and agency costs. Paul Rubin (1978)
  • 5. applied the insights of transaction cost economics to explain the existence of franchising as a business form. Rubin argued that existing explanations for use of the franchise form based on capital constraints were implausible, and that insights from Coase’s (1937) theory of the firm better explain the existence of the franchise form. In addition, studies of franchise regulation illustrate how the regulation of the contractual relationship between franchisors and franchisees affects contracting and the organization of firms.2 ∗ Jonathan Klick (corresponding author), University of Pennsylvania Law School; Bruce Kobayashi, George Mason University School of Law; and Larry Ribstein, Uni- versity of Illinois College of Law. We thank Ted Eisenberg and Andreas Roider as well as the other participants at the 2011 JITE conference on “Testing Contracts.” 1 See Klein (1995) (discussing the economics of franchise contracts); Lafontaine and Masten (1995) (discussing literature generally); Brickley, Misra, and Van Horn (2006) (finding contract duration in franchise contracts is positively related to fran- chisee’s level of specific investments), Brickley (1999) (examining incidence of spe- cific contractual provisions in franchise contracts). 2 See, e.g., Brickley, Dark, and Weisbach (1991), Muris and Beales (1994) (exam-
  • 6. ining state regulation of termination); Marvel (1995) (examining FTC regulation of gasoline franchising); Smith (1982) (examining state regulation of automobile dealers). Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics JITE 168 (2012), 38–53 © 2012 Mohr Siebeck – ISSN 0932- 4569 D e liv e re d b y P u b lis h in g T e ch
  • 9. o h r S ie b e ck The Effect of Contract Regulation on Franchising(2012) 39 The use of termination clauses has been central in much of this literature. Rubin (1978) and Klein (1995) both argue that termination clauses serve as part of a bond whereby a franchisee risks losing his rents if he engages in ex post opportunism. Brickley, Dark, and Weisbach (1991) test this idea using state laws that restrict termination clauses, generally finding support for the bonding hypothesis. However, this study relies on cross-sectional comparisons from which it is difficult to make causal inferences. Further, as we suggested in Klick, Kobayashi, and Ribstein (2009), it is surprising that these laws, on their own, have any effect on franchise activity given the ability of parties to contract around termination restrictions in many cases. In this article, we address both of these issues using some limited data on fran- chising in the fast-food industry. Using panel data, we examine
  • 10. the effects of the termination restriction law passed in Iowa in 1992 and the removal of a similar law in the District of Columbia in 1998. Panel data provide the opportunity to parse out idiosyncratic differences across states in isolating the effect of a given law in ways not possible in purely cross-sectional data. Also, these two particular laws are interesting in that the Iowa law severely restricted the ability of the parties to contract around the termination limitation, while the D.C. law, when it was in effect, did not foreclose the possibility of waiver or choice-of-law-and- forum clauses. Our examination of the effects of these law changes suggests that the Iowa law did affect the degree of franchise activity that occurred in Iowa. Given the high transaction costs created by restrictions on clauses that would undo the termina- tion law, the termination restriction appears to have reduced franchise activity. The D.C. termination law, on the other hand, which had no such restrictions, had am- biguous effects on franchising in the jurisdiction. This leaves open the possibility that parties simply contracted around the law, as would be suggested by the Coase theorem. On a methodological note, because our analysis focuses on very limited variation in the legal variable that provides our statistical identification, we explore a number
  • 11. of new methods for making statistical inferences. While these tools have yet to have much of an impact in the empirical law and economics literature, they deserve attention since the problems we face are quite common when investigating the effects of legal changes. In section 2, we briefly review the economic theory regarding the use of termina- tion clauses in franchise contract and we describe the existing empirical evidence regarding their effects. In section 3, we describe the panel data we collected. Sec- tion 4 presents our empirical results, while section 5 discusses the problem of statistical inference in these settings. We conclude in section 6. 2 Termination Clauses in Franchise Contracts As laid out in Rubin (1978) and Klein (1995), franchise contracts give rise to problems of opportunism. Poor performance on the part of a given franchisee generates a negative externality borne by the franchisor and other franchisees. This D e liv e re
  • 14. 4 :3 5 :2 5 C o p yr ig h t M o h r S ie b e ck J. Klick, B. H. Kobayashi, and L. E. Ribstein40 JITE 168 negative externality degrades the value of the trademark. Ex ante, franchisees would like to commit to a given level of performance, but this commitment is not credible.
  • 15. In order to make the commitment credible, the franchisee posts a bond through the payment of a franchise fee and makes other sunk investments, while agreeing to broad termination rights for the franchisor. In expectation, these expenditures will be recouped through a flow of future rents. As made clear in Klein (1995) as long as the net present discounted value of these future rents exceeds the gain available from cheating (i.e., poor performance), the franchisee will not shirk under these conditions, assuming the franchisor detects cheating perfectly. In the case where detection is imperfect, the size of the bond and sunk investments can be scaled to offset the detection problem. However, these broad termination rights may create an opportunism problem on the part of the franchisor. Specifically, the franchisor can engage in cream skimming in which it terminates contracts when a given franchise proves to be unexpectedly profitable for the franchisee. In such a scenario, the franchisor can resell the unit at terms more favorable to itself or run the unit directly. While reputational concerns may constrain this franchisor opportunism, if franchisees are poorly informed or make systematic mistakes, termination clauses may trade one form of opportunism for another. This cream-skimming concern has motivated a number of jurisdictions to restrict
  • 16. such clauses, requiring a showing of good cause for termination on the part of fran- chisors. If the termination clauses serve to reign in franchisee opportunism, limiting termination to good cause is likely to leave some opportunism unchecked in a world of incomplete contracts, litigation costs, and court error. On the margin, some fran- chise units will become economically unprofitable, leading the franchisor to reduce its activity, reducing social welfare in the process.3 If the cream-skimming concern is dominant, however, these laws could improve social welfare by constraining the franchisor’s opportunism. If these laws primarily serve to limit franchisor opportunism, the effect on fran- chising activity is ambiguous. If franchisees no longer fear ex post opportunism on the part of franchisors, they could be willing to open more franchises at a given set of terms. However, if the opportunism took the form of tricking franchisees into opening many poor locations in the hope of discovering a few unexpected prizes, termination restrictions could lead to a reduction of franchising. To test these competing hypotheses, Brickley, Dark, and Weisbach (1991) com- pare the extent of franchising in states that restrict termination and those that do not. They find a lower share of franchising in restricted states than in non-restricted states using cross-sectional data. To address the efficiency question, they sepa-
  • 17. rately analyze industries serving primarily non-repeat customers (where franchisee 3 Some units might be run by the franchisor at a lower, but still positive, profit. However, as in the Klein model, some units that cannot be run profitably by the fran- chisor due to its inability to control agency costs could be run profitably by a well incentivized franchisee whose opportunism is constrained. Once this constraint is re- duced, the unit becomes unprofitably regardless of which entity manages it. D e liv e re d b y P u b lis h in
  • 20. ig h t M o h r S ie b e ck The Effect of Contract Regulation on Franchising(2012) 41 opportunism is more likely to be a problem), finding the effect to be more pro- nounced in these industries. This suggests that franchisee opportunism concerns dominate concerns over cream skimming, and the termination restrictions affect organizational form. The restrictions then presumably have a negative effect on economic efficiency. They find complementary evidence using cross-sectional firm- level data. Cross-sectional studies, however, have significant limitations due to omitted vari- able biases. Specifically, law passage may be endogenous to other factors that affect franchising patterns. Modern panel data techniques,
  • 21. specifically differences- in-differences studies using fixed effects, can mitigate these concerns. If the portion of the omitted variables that is the source of the bias is time- invariant, this kind of research design can yield causal inferences. Brickley, Dark, and Weisbach (1991) could not implement such a design because of data limitations. Even if the omitted variable bias is generated by changing unobservable characteristics of a state, if those changes are linear, the bias can be controlled through the inclusion of state-specific trends. Another concern with the termination law analysis involves the ability of par- ties to contract around such laws. Brickley (2002) suggests that some contractual changes do occur in the face of these laws, finding that franchisors located in states with restrictions tend to use lower front-end fees and higher royalties, presumably spending more to monitor franchisee behavior. Again, these results are based only on cross-sectional data, so causal inference is problematic. However, even if the effects are causal, they are presumably not the parties’ first response to termination restrictions. Namely, as discussed above and in Klick, Kobayashi, and Ribstein (2009), in some states it would be simple to contractually avoid the effect of the statutory termination restrictions. Although states generally do not permit direct waiver of these restrictions, which are
  • 22. intended for the protection of one of the contracting parties, parties can achieve a similar effect through a clause providing that the contract is to be interpreted and enforced under the law of a state that does not regulate franchise termination. Under applicable choice-of-law rules, whether a court will enforce a choice-of-law clause depends on the contacts between the parties and transaction on the one hand and the chosen jurisdiction on the other, whether a state with closer contacts seeks to regulate the transaction, and on the nature of this regulation (O’Hara and Ribstein, 2009, ch. 3). Because courts have significant discretion under these rules whether to enforce another state’s restrictions, the parties might maximize the chance that the clause will be enforced by adding clauses to the agreement providing that the dispute will be decided by a court that is likely to enforce the parties’ choice-of-law clause, and that the parties consent to jurisdiction in the designated forum. Enforceability of such choice-of-forum and jurisdiction clauses has been sup- ported by the U.S. Supreme Court.4 Indeed, the Court’s 1985 ruling enforcing 4 M/S Bremen v. Zapata Off-Shore Co., 407 U.S. 1 (1972); Carnival Cruise Lines, Inc. v. Shute, 499 U.S. 585 (1991).
  • 26. J. Klick, B. H. Kobayashi, and L. E. Ribstein42 JITE 168 a consent-to-jurisdiction clause in a franchise contract5 provided an important im- petus to the enforcement of choice-of-forum and choice-of-law clauses in these contracts. U.S. federal courts quickly followed with cases enforcing choice-of-law clauses in these contracts.6 States could avoid the effect of these rulings by enacting statutory provisions explicitly voiding choice-of-law and choice-of-forum clauses. However, only two states, Washington and Iowa, void both types of provisions in their franchise protection statutes.7 Parties could avoid regulation of franchises located in other states by choosing the law of a non-regulating state and a forum that will enforce the contract’s choice-of-forum clause. Even if the franchisor is located in a state that does not enforce choice-of-law or choice- of-forum clauses, the franchisor can avoid the effect of franchise regulation of franchises located in states that do enforce the clauses (Klick, Kobayashi, and Ribstein, 2009). Use of choice-of-law-and-forum clauses is distinct from other types of contractual or organizational responses in that it does not require the firm to make costly tradeoffs. The effect of choice-of-law-and-forum clauses stems from inherent limits on states’ regulatory powers in a federal system, and can produce results closer
  • 27. to pure regulatory arbitrage than the courts in the regulating state are likely to permit under that state’s law (Kobayashi and Ribstein, 1999). The prior economics literature had completely ignored this availability of regulatory arbitrage. Given the parties’ ability to contract around termination restrictions using choice- of-law and choice-of-forum clauses, it would be surprising if such laws, on their own, would have any effect on franchise activity. Franchise contracts routinely contain contractual choice-of-law-and-forum clauses, and the courts have allowed such choices when not explicitly precluded by a state (Kobayashi and Ribstein, 1999; Klick, Kobayashi, and Ribstein, 2009). Our earlier empirical work in this area suggests the effectiveness of contractual choice of jurisdiction as a mechanism for regulatory arbitrage. Taking into account state variation in restricting choice-of- law-and-forum clauses, we found that termination restrictions only have an effect if the states’ statutes explicitly restrict use of contractual choice-of-law-and-forum clauses (Klick, Kobayashi, and Ribstein, 2009). Our previous work in this area uses panel data methods to mitigate the endo- geneity concerns of the existing economics literature and it does allow for a more complete consideration of the heterogeneity in the strictness of the state termination restrictions. However, it relies on a fairly blunt metric of
  • 28. franchise activity, namely employment in industries with a high degree of franchising in them. In this article, we instead rely on firm-level franchising data. To address the issue of legal heterogeneity, we focus on two very different termi- nation restrictions. First we examine the termination restriction introduced in Iowa in 5 Burger King v. Rudzewicz, 471 U.S. 462 (1985). 6 Tele-Save Merchandising v. Consumers Distributing, 814 F.2d 1120 (6th Cir. 1987); Modern Computer Systems, Inc. v. Modern Banking Systems, Inc., 871 F.2d 734 (8th Cir. 1989). 7 For a comprehensive listing of State Franchise Protection Statutes, see Klick, Kobayashi, and Ribstein (2009, Table 1). D e liv e re d b y P
  • 31. :2 5 C o p yr ig h t M o h r S ie b e ck The Effect of Contract Regulation on Franchising(2012) 43 1992 which also included restrictions on waiver, choice-of-law, and choice-of-forum clauses. These additional restrictions make it very difficult to avoid the termination restriction through contractual mechanisms, presumably leading to a relatively large change in franchising behavior. We also examine the federal repeal of Washington, D.C.’s termination restriction in 1998. The D.C. law was not
  • 32. one of the few jurisdic- tions restricting parties’ ability to avoid regulation through waiver, choice-of-law, or choice-of-forum clauses (see Klick, Kobayashi, and Ribstein, 2009, Table 1).8 Presumably then, if termination clauses serve some economic purpose, the parties could have easily contracted around the restriction through one of these other av- enues, suggesting that any change in franchising behavior occurring after repeal would likely be small. Unfortunately, we have no way of testing the efficiency effects of any of these laws, lacking a comparison between repeat and non-repeat businesses. Instead, we merely aim to provide a better design for causal inference and to highlight the importance of more careful consideration of legal subtleties. 3 Franchising Data The data used by Brickley, Dark, and Weisbach (1991) came from the U.S. De- partment of Commerce publication “Franchising in the Economy.” These data were not published beyond 1986, requiring us to find a different data source for our analysis. We examined the Uniform Franchise Offering Circular (UFOC) filed by a number of fast-food franchisors with the Maryland Attorney General’s Office. The UFOC
  • 33. (since renamed the Franchise Disclosure Document), which is a required filing in 15 states contains an item (item 20) that discloses the number of outlets franchised and franchisor operated in each state. Unfortunately, for our purposes, this item was only required beginning in 1992, although some franchisors began disclosing this information in the preceding years. Of the large fast-food franchisors, the only ones that included the information for item 20 before 1992 were Burger King (disclosure beginning in 1990) and Domino’s Pizza (disclosure beginning in 1989). We focus much of our analysis on those two franchisors. Because of its importance in the industry, we also include McDonald’s 8 Both the Iowa and D.C. statutes required notice and good cause for a franchise to terminate its contract with a franchisee. Both statutes also required cause for non- renewal, and allowed a franchisee a right to cure defects. Thus, with respect to the ter- mination/renewal provisions, both the Iowa and D.C. statutes were substantively simi- lar. The Iowa statute did include other substantive provisions not included in the D.C. statute, including franchisor liability for encroachment and a provision that allowed a franchisor to purchase supplies, equipment, services, etc. from sources of the fran- chisee’s choosing. The encroachment provisions originally enacted in the 1992 Iowa statute were weakened in a 1995 amendment to the statute. See
  • 34. Iowa Code § 523H (1992, 1995). D e liv e re d b y P u b lis h in g T e ch n o lo g
  • 37. ie b e ck J. Klick, B. H. Kobayashi, and L. E. Ribstein44 JITE 168 Table 1 Number of Franchised Units per State Firm Mean St. dev. IA 1992 count DC 1998 count Burger King 120 128 47 9 Domino’s Pizza 73 73 17 13 McDonald’s 188 188 88 27 Note: Data from UFOC item 20 filed with Maryland Attorney General’s Office. Sample covers 1990–2000 for Burger King, 1989–2000 for Domino’s Pizza, and 1992–2000 for McDonald’s. (disclosure beginning in 1992) in our analysis of the D.C. termination restriction.9 Descriptive statistics for these firms are presented in Table 1. 4 Contract Regulations (Sometimes) Affect Behavior Our research design examines the number of franchised units in a given state during a given year, controlling for deflated state per capita income, as well as state- and year-fixed effects. We did examine other control variables, primarily demographic
  • 38. controls, we chose to omit them in the results presented because (1) they did not affect the results of interest and (2) because demographic data are linearly interpolated between census years, inclusion of these data in the regressions is unlikely to be informative beyond the specifications that also include linear state- specific trends. Because of concerns regarding scale differences across states, we present re- gression specifications that use both the level and the natural log of the dependent variable. Our regressor of interest, the termination restriction, is an indicator taking the value of 1 if the state restricted the application of termination clauses in fran- chise contracts and 0 otherwise. To account for dependence in our data, we cluster standard errors at the state level. In our first set of results, we pool the effect of the Iowa and the Washington, D.C. restrictions in Table 2. In addition to a general lack of statistical significance, it is apparent that there is no robust effect of the laws across the two firms we examined. However, given the discussion above about the importance of considering how firms might be able to contract around laws such as these, we proceed to examine the two laws separately. First we examine the highly restrictive Iowa law which prohibits the application of not only termination clauses, but it also explicitly prohibits
  • 39. the application of waiver, choice-of-law, and choice-of-forum clauses. We present these results in Table 3.10 9 We examined a number of other franchisors in the context of the D.C. law, find- ing qualitatively similar results to those that follow. 10 Note that the Table 3 and Table 4 regressions omit observations from Washing- ton, D.C. We do this to avoid the inclusion of any effects arising from the D.C. termi- nation restriction that will be examined later. D e liv e re d b y P u b lis h in
  • 42. yr ig h t M o h r S ie b e ck The Effect of Contract Regulation on Franchising(2012) 45 Table 2 Effect of Termination Restrictions on Franchised Restaurants Burger King Domino’s Pizza Franchise ln(franchise Franchise ln(franchise units units) units units) Termination 8.38 −0.08∗ ∗ ∗ −0.11 −0.11 restriction (19.53) (0.02) (5.17) (0.21) State effects yes yes yes yes Year effects yes yes yes yes State trends no no no no Notes: ∗ ∗ ∗ p < 0.01 (against two-sided test of zero effect); ∗ ∗ p < 0.05 (against two-sided
  • 43. test of zero effect); ∗ p < 0.10 (against two-sided test of zero effect); standard errors in parentheses clustered at state level. Sample includes the 50 states and the District of Columbia for the period 1990–2000 (n = 561) for Burger King and 1989–2000 for Domi- no’s Pizza (n = 612). Regressions control for constant state per capita income. Franchise data come from UFOC’s (item 20) filed with Maryland State Attorney General’s Office. Table 3 Effect of 1992 Iowa Termination Restriction on Franchised Restaurants Burger King Domino’s Pizza Franchise ln(franchise Franchise ln(franchise units units) units units) Termination −22.59 −0.06 −7.14 −0.40 restriction (6.30)∗ ∗ ∗ (0.04) (3.50)∗ ∗ (0.04)∗ ∗ ∗ State effects yes yes yes yes Year effects yes yes yes yes State trends no no no no Notes: ∗ ∗ ∗ p < 0.01 (against two-sided test of zero effect); ∗ ∗ p < 0.05 (against two-sided test of zero effect); ∗ p < 0.10 (against two-sided test of zero effect); standard errors in parentheses clustered at state level. Sample includes the 50 states for the period 1990–2000 (n = 550) for Burger King and 1989–2000 for Domino’s Pizza (n = 600). Regressions con- trol for constant state per capita income. Franchise data come from UFOC’s (item 20) filed
  • 44. with Maryland State Attorney General’s Office. We find that the effect of the Iowa law is uniformly negative and the effect is generally statistically significant for both firms in both the log and the level specifications. The point estimates suggest that the Iowa restriction was associated with a decline in Burger King franchises, relative to the Iowa baseline and relative to the amount of franchising occurring elsewhere, of about 46%. For Domino’s Pizza, the comparable magnitude is 33%. While the fixed-effects model accounts for constant unobserved heterogeneity across states that could lead to omitted variables bias in pure cross-sectional com- D e liv e re d b y P u b
  • 47. C o p yr ig h t M o h r S ie b e ck J. Klick, B. H. Kobayashi, and L. E. Ribstein46 JITE 168 Table 4 Effect of 1992 Iowa Termination Restriction on Franchised Restaurants: Allowing for State Trends Burger King Domino’s Pizza Franchise ln(franchise Franchise ln(franchise units units) units units) Termination −8.31 −0.13 −15.70 −0.92
  • 48. restriction (1.42)∗ ∗ ∗ (0.04)∗ ∗ ∗ (2.53)∗ ∗ ∗ (0.05)∗ ∗ ∗ State effects yes yes yes yes Year effects yes yes yes yes State trends yes yes yes yes Notes: ∗ ∗ ∗ p < 0.01 (against two-sided test of zero effect); ∗ ∗ p < 0.05 (against two-sided test of zero effect); ∗ p < 0.10 (against two-sided test of zero effect); standard errors in parentheses clustered at state level. Sample includes the 50 states for the period 1990–2000 (n = 550) for Burger King and 1989–2000 for Domino’s Pizza (n = 600). Regressions con- trol for constant state per capita income. Franchise data come from UFOC’s (item 20) filed with Maryland State Attorney General’s Office. parisons, it does not account for changing heterogeneity that could be associated both with law adoption and franchising. To attempt to mitigate this concern, we present regressions that include linear state-specific trends in Table 4. Once again, we find uniformly negative and statistically significant effects associ- ated with the Iowa termination restriction, relative to Iowa’s baseline and relative to developments in franchising elsewhere. As for the endogeneity concerns, the trend specifications suggest, if anything, that the earlier results may have actually been understated. Moving on to the Washington, D.C. termination restriction, which was repealed
  • 49. by the U.S. Congress in 1998, we note that compared to the Iowa law, the D.C. law is relatively easy to contract around since it contains no explicit limitation on waiver, choice-of-law, or choice-of-forum clauses. While it is possible that a court could read such limitations into any transaction, especially with respect to waiver clauses, it is by no means guaranteed.11 Because of this, we predict that any effect of the law is likely to be smaller and less precise than that associated with the Iowa law. We present the first set of D.C. results in Table 5. In one case the effect of the D.C. law is of a different sign than that associated with the Iowa law passage. While this may be suggestive that the D.C. law is different in unexpected ways than the Iowa law, the sign difference within the Burger King specifications could be suggestive of a general lack of robustness. We see more evidence of this when we examine regressions that include state-specific linear trends in Table 6. 11 For a discussion of these issues, see Klick, Kobayashi, and Ribstein (2009). D e liv e
  • 52. 4 1 4 :3 5 :2 5 C o p yr ig h t M o h r S ie b e ck The Effect of Contract Regulation on Franchising(2012) 47 Table 5 Effect of 1998 D.C. Termination Restriction Repeal on
  • 53. Franchised Restaurants Burger King Domino’s Pizza Franchise ln(franchise Franchise ln(franchise units units) units units) Termination 31.41 −0.11 6.77 0.17 restriction (5.36)∗ ∗ ∗ (0.03)∗ ∗ ∗ (2.93)∗ ∗ (0.03)∗ ∗ ∗ State effects yes yes yes yes Year effects yes yes yes yes State trends no no no no Notes: ∗ ∗ ∗ p < 0.01 (against two-sided test of zero effect); ∗ ∗ p < 0.05 (against two-sided test of zero effect); ∗ p < 0.10 (against two-sided test of zero effect); standard errors in parentheses clustered at state level. Sample includes 49 states (Iowa is omitted) and the District of Columbia for the period 1990–2000 (n = 550) for Burger King and 1989–2000 for Domino’s Pizza (n = 600). Regressions control for constant state per capita income. Franchise data come from UFOC’s (item 20) filed with Maryland State Attorney General’s Office. Table 6 Effect of 1998 D.C. Termination Restriction Repeal on Franchised Restaurants: Allowing for State Trends Burger King Domino’s Pizza Franchise ln(franchise Franchise ln(franchise
  • 54. units units) units units) Termination −3.51 −0.54 4.32 −0.05 restriction (1.70)∗ ∗ (0.03)∗ ∗ ∗ (1.79)∗ ∗ (0.05) State effects yes yes yes yes Year effects yes yes yes yes State trends yes yes yes yes Notes: ∗ ∗ ∗ p < 0.01 (against two-sided test of zero effect); ∗ ∗ p < 0.05 (against two-sided test of zero effect); ∗ p < 0.10 (against two-sided test of zero effect); standard errors in parentheses clustered at state level. Sample includes 49 states (Iowa is omitted) and the District of Columbia for the period 1990–2000 (n = 550) for Burger King and 1989–2000 for Domino’s Pizza (n = 600). Regressions control for constant state per capita income. Franchise data come from UFOC’s (item 20) filed with Maryland State Attorney General’s Office. What is most evident is the lack of stability in the parameter estimates. Between Tables 5 and 6, we see large changes in the magnitude of the coefficients as well as sign changes. Within each table as well, there are indications of fragility of the estimates. We take this as weak evidence of the lesser effect of the D.C. law, though, D e liv
  • 57. 0 1 4 1 4 :3 5 :2 5 C o p yr ig h t M o h r S ie b e ck J. Klick, B. H. Kobayashi, and L. E. Ribstein48 JITE 168
  • 58. of course, it could also be a sign of model misspecification or other empirical problems.12 We see a similar lack of robustness if we examine the effect of the D.C. law’s repeal on the franchising activities of McDonald’s in Table 7. Table 7 Effect of 1998 D.C. Termination Restriction Repeal on Franchised McDonald’s Restaurants McDonald’s Franchise ln(franchise Franchise ln(franchise units units) units units) Termination 26.94 0.07 −20.09 −0.22 restriction (5.30)∗ ∗ ∗ (0.02)∗ ∗ ∗ (4.20)∗ ∗ ∗ (0.02)∗ ∗ ∗ State effects yes yes yes yes Year effects yes yes yes yes State trends no no yes yes Notes: ∗ ∗ ∗ p < 0.01 (against two-sided test of zero effect); ∗ ∗ p < 0.05 (against two-sided test of zero effect); ∗ p < 0.10 (against two-sided test of zero effect); standard errors in parentheses clustered at state level. Sample includes 49 states (Iowa is omitted) and the District of Columbia for the period 1992–2000 (n = 450). Regressions control for constant state per capita income. Franchise data come from UFOC’s (item 20) filed with Maryland State Attorney General’s Office.
  • 59. From these analyses, the best estimate is that the Iowa termination restriction had a significantly negative, in terms of both statistical significance and economic importance, effect on franchising, while the weaker D.C. law did not have a clear effect. This is consistent with the notion that contractual regulations only bite when it is difficult to contract around them. This point may seem trivial, but it is one that has been missed in the voluminous economics literature on franchising. While we believe we have made methodological and substantive improvements in the analysis in this field, our data do not allow us to investigate the economic efficiency of termination clauses or laws that disallow them. The laws do seem to affect economic behavior when they increase the costs of contracting around them. 12 As Roider (2012) makes clear, failure to account for trends can be a source of misspecification. Our primary concern here is the lack of a uniform effect of the law in terms of sign both across firms and across specifications. This kind of fragility sug- gests that we cannot make an inference about the effect of the law with any degree of confidence. Eisenberg (2012) suggests, based on graphical analyses, that the problem may be one of a failure to find decent counterfactuals in the available data.
  • 63. b e ck The Effect of Contract Regulation on Franchising(2012) 49 5 Problems of Inference Drawing inferences about a single law change is complicated for both intuitive and more technical reasons. One intuitive concern involves the choice of counterfactuals against which to judge the effect of the Iowa law. In a sense, the preceding analysis compares the experience of Iowa to the pooled experience of the rest of the U.S. This may be problematic in that Iowa might simply have been following regional trends that are obscured when compared to the rest of the country. To mitigate this concern, we performed the same analysis restricting attention to the Midwestern states in Table 8. For brevity, we present only the log specifications. Table 8 Effect of 1992 Iowa Termination Restriction on Franchised Restaurants: Midwest Burger King Domino’s Pizza ln(franchise ln(franchise ln(franchise ln(franchise units) units) units) units) Termination −0.12 −0.17 −0.24 −0.80
  • 64. restriction (0.05)∗ (0.04)∗ ∗ ∗ (0.05)∗ ∗ ∗ (0.05)∗ ∗ ∗ State effects yes yes yes yes Year effects yes yes yes yes State trends no yes no yes Notes: ∗ ∗ ∗ p < 0.01 (against two-sided test of zero effect); ∗ ∗ p < 0.05 (against two-sided test of zero effect); ∗ p < 0.10 (against two-sided test of zero effect); standard errors in parentheses clustered at state level. Sample includes the 12 Midwestern states for the period 1990–2000 (n = 132) for Burger King and 1989–2000 for Domino’s Pizza (n = 144). Re- gressions control for constant state per capita income. Franchise data come from UFOC’s (item 20) filed with Maryland State Attorney General’s Office. Examining just the Midwest, we find no evidence that the earlier analysis was misleading. In this restricted sample, we find uniformly negative effects of the Iowa law, and the magnitude of the effect is comparable to that found earlier. Also, despite the large decline in sample size, we continue to find statistically significant effects. Another worry that arises is one of dependence. Applied empirical economists have recognized the concerns about dependence at least since Bertrand, Duflo, and Mullainathan (2004) which suggested clustering standard errors at the state level in policy analyses such as this one. The concern there is that many eco- nomic series exhibit serial correlation and laws themselves are
  • 65. sticky rather than randomly implemented or repealed each period. In such applications, standard errors can be severely understated when there is positive dependence (or over- stated when there is negative dependence). Clustering accounts for this depen- dence in certain circumstances by inflating or deflating the standard error estimates accordingly. D e liv e re d b y P u b lis h in g T
  • 68. t M o h r S ie b e ck J. Klick, B. H. Kobayashi, and L. E. Ribstein50 JITE 168 Rather less attention has been paid to within period dependence. That is, in the current context, if Burger King has some national strategy that affects its activities in all states but is not sufficiently accounted for by the control variables (specifically the year-fixed effects) state observations within a given year will not be conditionally independent. This could lead to problems of inference due to incorrectly calculated standard errors. Cameron, Gelbach, and Miller (2011) provide a procedure to ac- count for this multi-way clustering. We present our estimates with these standard errors in Table 9. Table 9 Effect of 1992 Iowa Termination Restriction on Franchised Restaurants:
  • 69. Inference Concerns Burger King Domino’s Pizza ln(franchise ln(franchise ln(franchise ln(franchise units) units) units) units) Termination −0.06 −0.06 −0.40 −0.40 restriction (0.04) (0.04) (0.04)∗ ∗ ∗ (0.10)∗ ∗ ∗ State effects yes yes yes yes Year effects yes yes yes yes State trends no no no no Clustering state multi-way state multi-way (state and year) (state and year) Notes: ∗ ∗ ∗ p < 0.01 (against two-sided test of zero effect); ∗ ∗ p < 0.05 (against two-sided test of zero effect); ∗ p < 0.10 (against two-sided test of zero effect). Sample includes the 50 states for the period 1990–2000 (n = 550) for Burger King and 1989–2000 for Domino’s Pizza (n = 600). Regressions control for constant state per capita income. Franchise data come from UFOC’s (item 20) filed with Maryland State Attorney General’s Office. We see that while the more sophisticated approach changes little with respect to Burger King, the Domino’s coefficient’s standard error increases by more than a factor of two. Despite this, however, the effect is still statistically significant. A potentially larger problem involves statistical issues having to do with the very
  • 70. basis of statistical inference. The standard method of inference relies on asymptotic assumptions that may not be justified in small samples. Of particular concern here is the fact that our estimate of interest comes from a single law change. A single law change may not be sufficient to satisfy the assumptions supporting a central limit theorem justification for inference using the standard approach. If that is the case, inference in the standard way will only be valid if normality applies. This is obviously a very restrictive assumption. Recent work by Conley and Taber (2011) and Gelbach, Helland, and Klick (2011) investigates this problem of inference based on a small number of policy changes. The presentations and suggested approaches are quite similar. Both rely on the fact that, under the null hypothesis of a zero effect, the residuals for the non-treatment observations provide a statistically valid empirical distribution of the treatment D e liv e re d b
  • 73. :3 5 :2 5 C o p yr ig h t M o h r S ie b e ck The Effect of Contract Regulation on Franchising(2012) 51 effect coefficient under the null hypothesis. This empirical distribution can then be used to judge statistical significance based on how extreme the estimated treatment effect is relative to the residuals of the control observations.
  • 74. The SQ test of Gelbach, Helland, and Klick (2011), which they develop in the event study framework, simply compares the point estimate of the event effect to the distribution of residuals for non-event observations. In the current context, we compared the immediate effect of the Iowa law (i.e., the estimated law coefficient restricting attention to 1992 and before) to the residuals from the model for all non- Iowa observations. Using a one-tailed test, we found that the size of the Iowa law effect on Burger King was more negative than all but the most extremely negative 2% of non-Iowa residuals. If, instead, we use a two-tailed test which simply compares the magnitude of the effect to the magnitude of the residuals, it was less extreme than 12% of the residuals. For Domino’s, a similar application of the SQ test finds the effect of the Iowa law to be more extremely negative than all but 2% of the non- Iowa residuals, while a two-tailed test places the Iowa effect as being more extreme, in absolute value, than 3% of the non-Iowa residuals. The Conley and Taber approach, developed in the differences- in-differences con- text, estimates the treatment effect and compares it to a placebo effect occurring at the same time in each of the non-treatment entities. Using this approach, Burger King’s response to the Iowa law was more extremely negative than 87% of the
  • 75. observed placebo effects. In absolute value terms, it was more extreme than 81% of the placebo effects. For Domino’s, the comparable levels are 99% and 97%. These results are shown in Table 10. Table 10 Effect of 1992 Iowa Termination Restriction on Franchised Restaurants: Non-Parametric Inference Burger King Domino’s Pizza ln(franchise units) ln(franchise units) Immediate effect of restriction −0.91 −0.49 State effects yes yes Year effects yes yes State trends no no SQ test 1-sided rejects at 2nd percentile rejects at 2nd percentile SQ test 2-sided rejects at 12th percentile rejects at 3rd percentile C&T test 1-sided rejects at 13th percentile rejects at 1st percentile C&T test 2-sided rejects at 19th percentile rejects at 3rd percentile Notes: SQ test refers to Gelbach, Helland, and Klick (2010) and uses the residuals for all states except Iowa and the District of Columbia for the periods 1990–2000 for Burger King and 1989–2000 for Domino’s Pizza to construct the empirical test distribution. C&T refers to Conley and Taber (2011) and uses the 1992 residual for each state except Iowa and the
  • 76. District of Columbia to construct the empirical test distribution. D e liv e re d b y P u b lis h in g T e ch n o lo g y
  • 79. b e ck J. Klick, B. H. Kobayashi, and L. E. Ribstein52 JITE 168 While the non-parametric approaches to inference reduce confidence slightly in the statistical significance of the effect of the Iowa law on Burger King, they confirm the statistical significance of the effect on Domino’s. On the whole, these results suggest that the findings are unlikely to be the result of random variation. 6 Conclusion While the franchise form has been studied extensively, the literature exhibits many limitations. First, the empirical work in this area is almost exclusively cross- sectional. This leads to significant problems of causal inference. Second, economists have paid too little attention to the legal environment in which franchise contracts are interpreted and enforced. This article makes improvements in both of these areas, using panel data on the franchise activity of some large fast- food chains to examine the effect of laws limiting the use of termination clauses in franchise contracts. We also note that these termination laws can vary in their effect quite a bit from state to state depending on the degree to which parties can
  • 80. contract around the law. We show that there are very different effects of a termination law in Iowa that limited contractual avoidance of the law and a similar law in Washington, D.C. that did not limit these opportunities. Failure to recognize these differences limits the accuracy and the usefulness of previous work in the area. Some termination laws, specifically those that limit contractual work arounds, significantly affect franchise activity, while those that do not limit avoidance have ambiguous effects. References Bertrand, M., E. Duflo, and S. Mullainathan (2004), “How Much Should we Trust Differences- in-Differences Estimates?” The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 119, 249–275. Brickley, J. (1999), “Incentive Conflicts and Contractual Restraints: Evidence from Franchis- ing,” The Journal of Law & Economics, 37, 745–774. — (2002), “Royalty Rates and Upfront Fees in Share Contracts: Evidence from Franchising,” The Journal of Law, Economics, & Organization, 18, 511–535. —, F. Dark, and M. Weisbach (1991), “The Economic Effects of Franchise Termination Laws,” The Journal of Law & Economics, 34, 101–132. —, S. Misra, and R. Van Horn (2006), “Contract Duration: Evidence from Franchising,” The Journal of Law & Economics, 49, 173–196.
  • 81. Cameron, C., J. Gelbach, and D. Miller (2011), “Robust Inference with Multi-Way Cluster- ing,” Journal of Business and Economic Statistics, 29, 238–249. Coase, R. (1937), “The Nature of the Firm,” Economica, 4, 386– 405. Conley, T., and C. Taber (2011), “Inference with Difference in Differences with a Small Number of Policy Changes,” The Review of Economics and Statistics, 93, 113–125. Eisenberg, T. (2012), “Methodological Issues in the Analysis of Longitudinal Data: Com- ment,” Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics (JITE), 168(1), 54–57. Gelbach, J., E. Helland, and J. Klick (2011), “Valid Inference in Single Firm, Single-Event Studies,” Working Paper, available at http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id =1442222. Klein, B. (1995), “The Economics of Franchise Contracts,” Journal of Corporate Finance, 2, 9–37. http://www.ingentaconnect.com/content/external- references?article=0929-1199()2L.9[aid=9284503] http://www.ingentaconnect.com/content/external- references?article=0929-1199()2L.9[aid=9284503] http://www.ingentaconnect.com/content/external- references?article=0013-0427()4L.386[aid=42424] http://www.ingentaconnect.com/content/external- references?article=0735-0015()29L.238[aid=9840269]
  • 85. o h r S ie b e ck The Effect of Contract Regulation on Franchising(2012) 53 Klick, J., B. Kobayashi, and L. Ribstein (2009), “Federalism, Variation, and State Regulation of Franchise Termination,” Entrepreneurial Business Law Journal, 3, 355–379. Kobayashi, B. H., and L. E. Ribstein (1999), “Contract and Jurisdictional Freedom,” in: F. H. Buckley (ed.), The Fall and Rise of Freedom of Contract, Duke University Press, Durham (NC), pp. 325–349. Lafontaine, F., and S. Masten (1995), “Franchise Contracting, Organization, and Regulation: Introduction,” Journal of Corporate Finance, 2, 1–7. Marvel, H. (1995), “Tying, Franchising, and Gasoline Service Stations,” Journal of Corporate Finance, 2, 199–225. Muris, T., and H. Beales (1994), “State Regulation of Franchise Contracts,” unpublished Manuscript, George Mason University School of Law, Arlington
  • 86. (VA) and George Wash- ington University, Washington, DC. O’Hara, E. A., and L. E. Ribstein (2009), The Law Market, Oxford University Press, New York. Roider, A. (2012), “The Effect of Contract Regulation on Franchising: Comment,” Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics (JITE), 168(1), 58– 61. Rubin, P. (1978), “The Theory of the Firm and the Structure of the Franchise Contract,” The Journal of Law & Economics, 21, 223–233. Smith, R. (1982), “Franchise Regulation: An Economic Analysis of State Restrictions on Automobile Distribution,” The Journal of Law & Economics, 25, 125–157. Jonathan Klick Law School University of Pennsylvania 3400 Chestnut Street Philadelphia, PA 19104 U.S.A. E-mail: [email protected] Bruce H. Kobayashi School of Law George Mason University 3301 Fairfax Drive Arlington, VA 22201 U.S.A. E-mail:
  • 87. [email protected] Larry E. Ribstein College of Law University of Illinois 504 E. Pennsylvania Avenue Champaign, IL 61820 U.S.A. E-mail: [email protected] http://www.ingentaconnect.com/content/external- references?article=0022-2186()21L.223[aid=223108] http://www.ingentaconnect.com/content/external- references?article=0022-2186()21L.223[aid=223108] http://www.ingentaconnect.com/content/external- references?article=0929-1199()2L.199[aid=9840275] http://www.ingentaconnect.com/content/external- references?article=0929-1199()2L.199[aid=9840275] http://www.ingentaconnect.com/content/external- references?article=0929-1199()2L.1[aid=9840276] http://www.ingentaconnect.com/content/external- references?article=0932-4569()168L.58[aid=9840278] http://www.ingentaconnect.com/content/external- references?article=0932-4569()168L.58[aid=9840278] Instructions for Academic article critique #2 (please submit to Turnitin link above) You are assigned to read and critique the attached papers to be submitted at the end of week 4 ( Sunday before 11:59 PM). Academic research may provide helpful insights to practitioners. As a graduate student, one of the more important skills you will develop, is the ability to read, understand, and critique an academic article. The length of your paper must be a minimum of 50 words for each section of the 7 sections, listed below. *Make sure to write down each of the questions in the order
  • 88. listed below as a heading (Title), followed by your answers that are specifically related to the question. DO NOT MIX THEM ALL TOGETHER. ASSIGNMENT FORMAT: For this assignment you need to prepare and submit a critique of the attached article in week 4 under the assignment # 2 in ulearn. Your critique must answer the following questions: 1. What was the intent of this research? 2. How was the research conducted (method)? 3. What was the sample for this research, and how was it determined? 4. What were the conclusions of the article? 5. Is this research actionable? In other words, could it be put into use in any practical way in a Franchisee or Franchisor business? 6. What in this article did you find most important? 7. What in this article did you find least important? Your paper needs to meet the following formatting requirements: *Make sure to write down each of the questions in an order listed above, followed by your answers that are specifically related to the question. DO NOT MIX THEM ALL TOGETHER • Microsoft Word Document • Margins 1 inch in each side, 1.5 top and bottom. • Double spaced • Any citations in text in APA 6th Edition format. • References at the end of your critique, also in APA 6th edition format. • No spelling errors • No grammatical errors • A Turnitin Originality Score of 25% or less (in other words, more than 75% of the paper must be in your own words • Your Article Critique must be submitted via the Turnitin link before 11:59PM on Sunday of the week assigned