SlideShare a Scribd company logo
1 of 20
Download to read offline
1+ Governmenl
04 Canada
Canac;,an
FOleSlry
se~.
Gouvernemenl
du Canada
Service
canad'en des
forets
Benefit-cost analysis of
forestry investment
G. Alex Fraser
Information Report BC-X-275
PacifiC Forestry Centre
Benefit-cost analysis of
forestry investment
G. Alex Fraser
Canadian Forestry Service
Pacific Forestry Centre
BC-X-275
1985
Canadian Forestry Service
Pacific Forestry Centre
506 West Burnside Road
Victoria, B.C.
V8Z IM5
~J Minister of Supply & Services Canada, 1985
ISSN 0705-3274
ISBN 0-662-14414-7
Cat. No. Fo46-17/275E
Abstract
This report reviews the development and applica-
tion of benefit-cost analysis to forestry invest-
ments. By use of examples, it leads the reader
through a discussion of measurement of costs
and benefits, discounting, and the sensitivity of
the method to changes in the underlying assump-
tions, and clearly states the limitations of benefit-
cost analysis.
3
Resume
11 s'agit d'une etude de relaboration de l'analyse
coOts-avantages et de son application aux inves-
tissements forestiers. A l'aide d'exemples, l'au-
teur explique la methode d'analyse coOts-
avantages, les techniques d'actualisation et la
degre de sensibilite de la methode ala variation
des hypotheses fondamentales. En outre, il in-
dique clairement les limites de cette methode
d'analyse.
5
Table of Contents
Page
Abstract/Resume 3
Introduction 6
Description of the projects 6
National income benefits 7
National income costs...................................................... 7
Present discounted values 8
Sensitivity analysis 8
Price trends............................................................. 8
Technology change 9
Shadow pricing........................................................ 9
Limitations and other considerations 10
Summary and conclusions 11
Bibliography 12
Appendix 1 17
Appendix 2 19
Introduction
In 1981, the federal cabinet endorsed, in princi-
ple, a nlajor push to increase timber supplies
through intensive forest renewal and manage-
nlent. The proposed nlechanism for program
delivery was a new series of federal/provincial
forest developnlent agreenlents. Negotiations
with the provinces began in late 1982 and, at this
tinle, all except that with Newfoundland have
been signed.
At both the negotiation stage and later when final
progranl approval is requested, there are many
elenlents of choice. Not all projects which can im-
prove the yield of the forests can be carried out
within a linlited budget, and specific projects or
areas of focus for agreenlents nlust be selected.
Sinlilarly, Cabinet and Treasury Board cannot ap-
prove all developnlent progranls which will inl-
prove the well-being of Canadians within a linlit-
ed budget. Forest renewal nlust conlpete with pri-
orities in other resource sectors as well as with
social policy. There is a need to choose between
alternatives and to set levels of funding and
effort.
In this type of selection process, benefit-cost
analysis is a potentially powerful tool. It is a sys-
tenlatic nleans of identifying and evaluating the
relatiye nlerits of alternative in vestnlent oppor-
tunities. In spite of this, little use has been nlade
of benefit-cost analysis in forest investnlent deci-
sion nlaking.
This reluctance to use benefit-cost analysis stenlS
partly fronl confusion regarding procedure. Bene-
fit-cost analysis is conlplex and there is considera-
ble debate on a nunlber of inlportant aspects of
the analysis. There is uncertainty regarding as-
sunlptions, and inconsistency and sometinles
errors in practice. Although the Federal Treasury
Board recognized these problenls and has
pronloted consistency through published guide-
lines, confusion renlains in areas such as forest
renewal and nlanagenlent.
The main intent of this paper is to illustrate
proper benefit-cost methodology applied to a
forest investment decision. Specifically, two hy-
pothetical forest renewal and management pro-
jects are analyzed. Many of the numbers used in
this analysis are rough approximations. Rather
6
than the specific results, the topic of importance
here is the deriviation of an appropriate frame-
work for analysis and the illustration of the in-
formation requirements. A heavy emphasis is
placed on sensitivity analysis in order to identify
the key factors which influence the results and to
determine the circumstances under which as-
sumptions can be validly varied. Also, the limita-
tions of the efficiency analysis are considered,
and alternative ways of incorporating non-
efficiency project impacts are explored.
Description of the projects
The area subject to the two silvicultural treat-
nlents is assumed to be one hectare in both cases.
Also, the land in both cases is assumed to be
located in the Vancouver Forest Region and the
grade of land is Site I (the highest classification in
the B.C. Ministry of Forests inventory of forest
land). In effect, it is the nlost productive forest
land in the province. In the first case, due to a
failure to replant after initial harvesting, the site
has been invaded and covered by noncommercial
brush. In the second case, a dense stand of
juvenile Douglas-fir aged 11 years has become es-
tablished on the site.
The first hypothetical silviculture project is a
reforestation project involving several distinct
steps. First, the present noncommercial cover
must be removed and destroyed without harming
the soils. Second, within one year of this site
rehabilitation, planting takes place. Finally, four
years after planting, brushing and weeding are re-
quired to remove the resurgence of undesirable
competitive brush growth. Each different step in
the project varies in the mix of capital and labor
used. For example, site rehabilitation is capital
intensive, requiring the use of specialized, expen-
sive equipment, whereas planting is labor inten-
sive. Brushing and weeding can be done either
manually or chemically and the labor intensity of
the operation depends upon choice.
The second hypothetical silviculture project in-
volves an integrated progranl of juvenile spacing
and fertilization. Spacing involves the selection
of superior trees and the removal of the less
valuable trees, while fertilization accelerates
growth. An integrated program is evaluated be-
cause fertilization and spacing are complemen-
tary, i.e., their joint impact is greater than the
sum of their separate impacts. Like the reforesta-
tion project, the mix of capital and labor varies
with the project phase. While spacing is largely a
labor-intensive operation, fertilization is largely
capital-intensive and requires a helicopter deliv-
ery system.
National income benefits
The national income benefit of a project is the
value of the goods and services produced over
and above that which would exist without the
project. In the first project, without silviculture,
the commercial productivity of the land would be
zero. Since the area has been invaded by brush,
the establishment of a commercial stand of
timber on the site without investment is improba-
ble. Consequently, the benefits amount to the
full value of the commercial timber harvest from
the site. This, in turn, depends on the age at har-
vest and the species planted.
It is assumed that Douglas-fir was the species
chosen for planting on the basis of the relative
productivity of the land, and that age 55 is the
selected harvest age. The expected harvest from
a planted class 1 site in the Vancouver Forest
region is 750 m3/ha at age 551
.
The volume benefit from a juvenile spacing and
fertilization project is the increment to the ex-
pected harvest. Based on studies of the relative
impact of these activities, the expected total yield
would increase by 195 m 3/ha at age 55. The ex-
pected total yield of the site after juvenile spacing
and fertilization is 945 m3
/hal
.
The value of the harvest is affected by the quality
of output. As outlined in Table 1, the Vancouver
log market differentiates three grades of Douglas-
fir with five-year average prices (1981 dollars)
ranging from $38/m3 for grade #3 to $100/m3
for
1 Since there is no experience with mature planted forests or mature
spaced and fertilized stands, the expected harvest volume is not
known with precision. There is a wide variety of opinion on the im-
pacts of different silvicultural treatments. The figures used in this
analysis are tentative and certainly not subject to unanimous
agreement.
7
grade # 1. The overall average price for all grades
was $50/m3, indicating that the major proportion
of the volume sold on the log market was grade
# 3. However, silviculture is expected to improve
product quality. Both planting and spacing,
through control of stand density, can result in
larger trees which command premium prices.
Fertilization has a similar effect by stimulating
tree growth. For these reasons, it is assumed for
valuation purposes2 that the harvest from the
two hypothetical projects averages grade # 2.
On the basis of these assumptions, the national
income benefits of the two forest management
projects are outlined in Table 2. The benefit of
the reforestation project is simply the total value
of the eventual harvest from the reforested land.
The benefit of the spacing/fertilization project is
somewhat different, incorporating two elements.
First, the value of the incremental production is
relatively straightforward and is equivalent to the
reforestation case, However, a second benefit
from spacing and fertilization results from in-
creased value of the entire harvest from the treat-
ed land. To calculate this item, it has been as-
sumed that the harvest would have commanded
only average prices in the absence of treatment.
The $20 difference between this and the grade
# 2 average price is the estimated benefit from
quality improvement.
National income costs
The costs of silviculture investment represent
the value of real resources displaced from other
uses. These costs fall into two distinct categories.
The primary or direct costs are those goods and
services which are used in the silvicultural pro-
jects outlined above. Based on reported average
per hectare cost of silvicultural treatment in the
Vancouver forest region during 1981-1982, pro-
ject costs by category are estimated in Table 3.
2 Log market prices can be used to value project output only if the
market is competitive. If monopsonistic elements are present,
market prices may be held below a competitive market equilibrium.
In this event, the result would be an underestimate of project bene-
fits. In effect, benefits are missed further down the processing chain
which are also attributable to the silviculture investment. Although
there is some question regarding the competitiveness of the Van-
couver log market, these prices are assumed to be adequate in the
absence ofalternatives.
The second elenlent of national inconle cost is
the associated cost of harvesting the resource. In
valuing the benefits of the projects., the Vancouv-
er log nlarket price was used. This represents the
value of output after harvesting and delivery to
water. The estinlated average cost of harvesting
in the Vancouver Forest Region is $11.00/m3 .,
while the estinlated transport cost is $0.1 O/knl/
nl~3. Assunling a distance of 50 knl to water., the
total associated cost of harvesting and transporta-
tion for the reforestation project would be
$12 000 (1981)., incurred at year 55 following
planting. The associated cost of harvesting and
transportation for increnlental production fronl
the spacing/fertilization project would be $3120
(1981) incurred 44 years after treatnlent.
Present discounted values
The benefits and costs of any silviculture invest-
nlent are realized over different tinle periods.
While the nlajor direct costs are incurred early in
the project., the benefits are realized and the asso-
ciated costs are incurred nlany years after the ini-
tial in vestnlent. Also., there are substantial dif-
ferences between projects in the tinle flow of
benefits and costs. For exanl pIe., the direct costs
of backlog planting are spread over a five-year
period early in the project., while the benefits are
realized 55 years after the initial investnlent. In
the case of the spacing/fertilization project., all
direct costs are incurred within one year., while
the benefits are realized 44 years later. Society is
not indifferent to such variations. Delayed bene-
fits are less valuable because they are unavailable
for inlnlediate consunlption or reinvestnlent.
In benefit-cost analysis., the discount rate is the
nleans through which benefits and costs which
vary widely in tinling are conlpared. In effect.,
future benefits and future costs are adjusted
downwards to reflect their reduced value. There
is considerable debate anlong econonlists on the
appropriate concepts as well as the specific rate to
be used in the discounting process. The extensive
technical literature on this subject is sunlnlarized
in Appendix 1.
Federal Treasury Board Guidelines suggest that
present values be calculated on the basis of a
range of discount rates., including 5., 10 and 15(%.
In this analysis., calculations are made with a
8
range of rates between 5 and lO(Y() as this is suffi-
cient to illustrate the importance of discounting
to project evaluation.
The net benefits of the backlog reforestation pro-
jects are positive only with a 5(~) discount rate
(Table 4). The calculations indicate that the in-
ternal rate of return on investnlent (i.e.., the dis-
count rate which exactly equates benefits and
costs) lies sonlewhere between 5 and 6°/<) per
annunl. In contrast., the net benefits of the spac-
ing/fertilization project remain positive at a 7%
discount rate. The internal rate of return on the
spacing/fertilization investnlent lies somewhere
between 7 and 8(Y() per annum or approxinlately
2(Y!) greater than the return on the reforestation
investnlent. At any discount rate., the benefit-
cost ratio for the spacing/fertilization project con-
sistently exceeds that of the reforestation
project3.
Sensitivity analysis
The analysis to this point has been perfornled in
a very elenlentary franlework. There are nunler-
ous inlplicit assunlptions which can be changed
to reflect current nlarket conditions or possible
future industry trends. A nunlber of these possi-
ble variations are pursued here in order to test
the sensitivity of the results and to explain the
conditions under which such variations are valid.
a. Price trends
Tinlber is beconling increasingly scarce. Both the
denland for forest products and the denland for
alternative uses of forest land are increasing as
world population grows. Sonle current forest
land will be alienated fronl forest production in
the future. Also., as the renlaining stands of
:3 In the example pursued here, the three basic ranking criteria (i.e.,
Benefit-Cost Ratio, Level of Net Benefits and Internal Rate of
Return) result in consistent ranking. The benefit-cost ratio and net
benefits from the reforestation project exceed those of the spacing/
fertilization project at all discount rates. Also, the internal rate of
return of the spacing/fertilization project is higher. For technical
reasons, these three criteria need not result in the same ranking of
projects. Consistent ranking sometimes requires an adjustment pro-
cedure. In general, the level of net benefits is the preferred ranking
criterion in the absence of adjustment.
virgin timber are harvested, the future produc-
tivity of forest land will be lowered. It is conceiva-
ble that future decreases in supply in conjunction
with increases in demand will imcrease real
prices over the long term. There is undoubtedly
some upper limit to such trends beyond which al-
ternative materials are used or substitute mate-
rials are developed. However, even minor incre-
mental price increases can have a major cumula-
tive impact over periods in excess of 40 years.
A long-term analysis performed by the U.S.
Department of Agriculture Forest Service in
1982 (An Analysis of the Timber Situation in the
U.S., 1952-2030) estimated a trend increase in
real lumber prices of 0.7% per annum from the
year 1950 through to the mid 1970s. Also, in
their opinion., this probably reflects a lower limit
on future real price trends. Indeed, the trend in-
crease in lumber prices may already reflect a
more rapid increase in log prices. If returns to the
factors employed in lumber production remained
constant over the period, the increased revenue
would be passed down the processing chain with
a proportionately greater impact.
Table 5 presents the benefits and costs of silvicul-
ture investment assuming a 1(~, per annum trend
increase in real prices over the period until the
timber is harvested. Given this assumption,
gross benefits do increase substantially under all
discount rates. Net benefits from the reforesta-
tion projects are now positive under a 7% dis-
count rate while net benefits from the juvenile
spacing/fertilization project are now positive
under an 8(Yc, discount rate. The internal rate of
return on both investments has increased sub-
stantially. It is now approximately 7(~, for the
reforestation project, and between 8 and 90ft, for
the spacing/fertilization project. However", at any
given discount rate, the benefit-cost ratio and net
benefits for the spacing/fertilization project con-
sistently exceed those of the reforestation project.
b. Technological change
Another factor which can have a major impact
over long periods is technological change. Over
time, there is a tendency for capital and labor to
become more efficient in the production of
goods and services. In the context of the two hy-
pothetical projects, the major impact of tech-
nological change would be to lower the associated
costs of harvesting and transporting the timber.
9
Although technological change will undoubtedly
also lower the direct costs of intensive silviculture
investment, the major expenditures here take
place in the near future. Real cost reductions
would not be pronounced in the short term.
Table 6 presents the benefits and costs of silvicul-
ture investment, assuming a 1(~, per annum de-
crease in the real associated costs of harvesting
and transporting timber. In general, assumptions
regarding technological change make very little
difference to the results. Net benefits of the refor-
estation project change only marginally, and
remain positive only with a 50ft, discount rate4•
c. Shadow pricing
In the cost calculations to this stage, the
resources used in silviculture investment have
been valued at their full market price. This re-
flects an implicit assumption of full employment
in the markets for the inputs required. What if
there is a recession with extreme unemployment
in the forest industry? Alternatively, what if an
individual project is located in an area of high
unemployment or, in some other way, generates
jobs for unemployed people? Under such condi-
tions, it may be valid to "shadow price" the
resources used in the silviculture projects at
below their financial costs. However, a number
of practical issues should be addressed before
proceeding.
The timing of investment activities is an impor-
tant consideration. Some reforestation activities
such as brushing and weeding will not take place
for a number of years. Current market conditions
should not be projected too far in the future. If
the economy is at a cyclical low, present unem-
ployment rates are unlikely to persist. For this
reason, shadow pricing, in this illustration, was
only applied to the resources used in the first two
years of the reforestation project. In effect, it is
assumed that the rationale for shadow pricing is a
.. The output of the two projects has been valued at Vancouver log
market prices, and at the this stage the product is an intermediate
input to a sawmill, pulp mill or plywood and veneer operation. Tech-
nological change may result in additional cost saving further down
the processing chain. In a competitive market situation, the e co t
savings would be reflected in higher log market prices. This is an
additional and potentially significant benefit from technological
change which is not dealt with here.
general cyclical downturn in the economy.
Caution houJd be exercised in estimating the
potential of a project to reduce unemployment; it
is unlikely that all of the labor hired and capital
used will be currently unemployed. A one-to-one
relationship between jobs created and reduction
in unemployment occurs only where there is
very high unemployment and a relative abun-
dance of all required skills and equipment. Even
in times of extreme unemployment, shortages
can exist for specific skill categories and equip-
ment items. Also, unless hiring is strictly con-
trolled, there is uncertainty that the individuals
employed or equipment used will be drawn from
the pool of unemployed labor or capital.
Also, what specific shadow value should be at-
tached to a particular input? For example, an as-
sumption that the shadow price of unemployed
labor is zero implicitly attaches a zero value to lei-
sure, and this is not strictly true. Similarly, a zero
shadow price for capital equipment ignores the
deterioration of that equipment through use.
Bearing all of this in mind, a shadow value of
SOlVO of financial cost was attached to the capital
and labor employed in both projects for illustra-
tive purposes in this analysis,.
Finally, there is the problem of handling inter-
mediate inputs such as fuel and the seedlings
planted. For example, if two-year-old seedlings
were used in the reforestation project, labor and
capital market conditions may have substantially
changed. Also, labor and capital are a very small
element in the price of fuel. For these reasons, it
is best that these intermediate inputs be valued
at their full financial costs. For the reforestation
project, the fuel cost of the initial site rehabilita-
tion is assumed to be $250, and an additional
$250 is the estimated cost of seedlings for plant-
ing. For the spacing/fertilization project, the fuel
cost for helicopter delivery of fertilizer is as-
sumed to be $150.
Shadow pricing does substantially reduce the
direct costs of silviculture investment under all
discount rates (Table 7). The effects are partic-
ularly pronounced with the spacing/fertilization
project where direct costs are reduced to less
than 60% of their previous levels. The reason for
this is the more immediate nature of the invest-
ment. While spacing and fertilization take place
within one year, reforestation activities extend
10
over a considerable time period. Shadow pricing,
on the basis of current labor and capital market
conditions, has more leverage on the costs of the
spacing/fertilization project.
Limitations and other
considerations
Is the benefit-cost analysis described to this point
adequate for decision making?
So far, it has dealt only with the efficiency effects
of investment in silviculture. This dollars-
and-cents orientation of benefit-cost analysis is
often criticized, and it is certainly true that the
objectives and responsibilities of government
extend far beyond mere economic efficiency. For
example, equitable distribution of income and
improved quality of life are also fundamental
social concerns. In addition, there are technical
limitations with the efficiency analysis pursued
to this point.
With respect to technical limitations, certain as-
sumptions are implicit within a benefit-cost
framework which may not be valid in all circum-
stances. As a specific example, studies by the
British Columbia Ministry of Forests indicate
that the present level of timber harvest cannot be
maintained with the present level of silvicultural
investment. The potential long-term decline in
harvests could adversely effect the province as a
whole, and particularly those areas which are
almost solely dependent on the forest industry.
Within the framework of benefit-cost analysis,
there is an implicit assumption of a costless and
easy adjustment to such changed levels of
economic activity. However, this is unlikely to
be the case. In general, long-run decisions are
being made to invest in plant and equipment and
regarding location of residence, etc., on the as-
sumption of future continuity of timber supplies.
Given this fact, future timber shortages could
impose substantial social and economic costs on
future generations of British Columbians. Clear-
ly, avoidance, or at least reduction, of these
social and economic costs may be a significant
benefit of increased silviculture investment.
These potential benefits should be recognized.
With _respect to non-efficiency objectives of
government, the overall program and individual
projects within it may serve these to a greater or
lesser extent. For example, in the context of the
two hypothetical investment projects analyzed,
the reforestation project may generate employ-
ment for native Indians or some equally disad-
vantaged group, while the spacing/fertilization
project may have no similar impact. Also, the
reforestation project may have more beneficial
impacts on the quality of the environment by
eliminating an eyesore in a populated area~ To'
the extent that these other objectives of govern-
. ment are served better by the economically less-
efficient project, maximizing social rather than
economic efficiency may warrant its selection.
There are two general methods of dealing with
technical limitations and with non-efficiency ob-
jectives in the context of benefit-cost analysis.
First, an attempt can be made to integrate these
effects within the financial framework. For exam-
ple, the economic costs associated with falldown
could be estimated. In this case, not only the
direct but also the indirect (multiplier) impacts
are relevant. In addition, the distribution of im-
pacts between private and government sectors is
an important consideration. Also, as suggested
by Weisbrod (1968), weights can be assigned to
the distribution of project benefits. Thus, addi-
tional income to a low-income group may be
valued more highly than the same income to a
high-income group. Finally, attempts can be
made to value such nonmarket items as environ-
mental quality. The major problem with this ap-
proach is the requirement for an explicit valua-
tion by the analyst, which may require a large
amount of information which is unavailable.
Beyond this, however, and regardless of the par-
ticular methods used to derive such values, this
procedure usurps the decision maker's role. In
effect, it pushes benefit-cost analysis beyond its
limited objective offacilitating rational choice.
A more satisfactory method of handling non-
efficiency effects and broader social concerns is
simply to document these impacts for parallel
presentation with the financial information. In
this procedure, the format of benefit-cost analysis
is useful for clarifying thinking. Objectives
beyond economic efficiency can be verbalized
and the extent to which various alternatives con-
tribute to their attainment can be investigated. In
effect, it encourages a more tightly argued and
quantitative approach to the impacts of a project
11
in social and environmental terms.
A particularly good illustration of this procedure
is given in the planning for Canada's west coast
salmon enhancement program. Here, several
high-priority objectives were identified including
income and employment for both Native Indians
and for residents in the less developed regions of
B.C. Various measures of effectiveness in attain-
ing these objectives were developed. Estimates
were then made of the contribution of individual
projects, as well as alternative programs, to the
achievement of these objectives. All of this infor-
mation was then provided in the program analysis
(Friedlaender and Fraser 1981).
Summary and conclusions
This paper has illustrated benefit-cost methodol-
ogy applied to two hypothetical silvicultural pro-
jects. Table 8 summarizes the net benefits under
the initial base case and with the various specified
assumptions examined. Under all assumptions,
the spacing/fertilization project is the superior in-
vestment with net benefits consistently exceed-
ing those of the reforestation project. However,
no single assumption investigated here is suffi-
cient to generate positive net benefits from
either project at the 10% discount rate recom-
mended by Federal Treasury Board for the evalu-
ation of public sector investments.
It must be remembered that the numbers used in
the analysis are rough approximations and the re-
sults should be interpreted with care. However,
the assumptions regarding both revenues and
costs are relatively generous reflecting invest-
ments which are undoubtedly superior to the
average forest investment in the province. The
two hypothetical projects are assumed to be locat-
ed on the best land, involve the most valuable
species and are located relatively near processing
facilities. In addition, the outcome of the projects
has been treated as certain. Realistically, project
benefits should be deflated to reflect the risks of
loss due to forest fire, insect or disease attack and
plantation failure.
It is resoundingly clear that the discount rate is of
overwhelming importance in determining the
financial viability of forest investments. For this
reason, both the theoretical determination of the
appropriate discount rate and the empirical evi-
d nc on it p in valu are discussed in Ap-
pendix I. A second appendix is included which in-
vestigates allowable cut effects. This is a contro-
versial method which has often been used in
forest investment analysis in order to circumvent
the discount rate problem. The validity of using
this method is questionable, but it is included for
completeness.
The results of the financial analysis underline the
importance of other non-efficiency benefits ofsil-
vicultural activities. It is likely that these broader
social concerns are the primary justification for
investment. However, this should not be used as
an excuse to ignore the relative efficiency of vari-
ous alternatives. Complete information on all of
the various benefits of the proposed investments
should be presented to decision makers, along
with the financial information, for their consider-
ation. The choice between various projects and
programs remains a basic political decision. How-
ever, benefit-cost analysis can facilitate rational
choice by ensuring that decision makers know
the relative merits of their various options.
Bibliography
Burgess, D.F. 1981. The Social Discount Rate
for Canada: Theory and Evidence. Canadian
Public Policy 7: 383-393.
Friedlaender, M. and A. Fraser. 1981. Social Im-
pacts and Economic Efficiency in Resource
Development Planning: The Case of Sal-
mon Enhancement in British Columbia, in
Tester and Mykes (eds.) Social Impact As-
sessment, Detselig Enterprises Ltd., Cal-
gary, Alberta.
Government of British Columbia. 1977. Guide-
lines for Benefit-Cost Analysis. Environ-
ment and Land Use Committee Secretariat,
Victoria, B.C.
Government of Canada. 1976. Benefit Cost Anal-
ysis Guide. Treasury Board Secretariat,
Ottawa.
12
Gaffney, M.M. 1957. Concepts of FinanaciaI
Maturity of Timber and Other Assets. A.E.
Info. Series #62, Dept. of Agric. Econom-
ics, North Carolina State College, Raleigh,
North Carolina.
Jenkins, G.P. 1972. The Measurement of Rates
of Return and Taxation from Private Capital
in Canada. Niskanen et al. (eds.) Benefit-
Cost and Policy Analysis, Chicago, Ill. pp.
211-227.
Jenkins, G.P. 1980. Discount Rates for Econom-
ic Appraisal of Public Sector Expenditures.
Canadian Public Policy 6: 549-555.
Jenkins, G.P. 1981. The Public Sector Discount
Rate for Canada: Some Further Observa-
tions.Canadian Public Policy 7: 399-407.
Kula, E. 1984. Derivation of Social Time Prefer-
ence Rates for the United States and
Canada. Q. J. Econ. 49: 873-882.
Mishan, E.J. 1976. Elements of Cost-Benefit
Analysis George Allen and Unwin Ltd.,
London, (2nd Edition).
Munger, J.A. and J.D. Edwards. 1970. The
Splendid but Superficial Contribution of
Conventional Economic Analysis to the
Management of Public Resources. The
Annals of Regional Science, pp. 29-37.
Reuber, G.L. and R.J. Wonnacott. 1961. The
Cost of Capital in Canada. Resources for
the Future, Washington, D.C.
Schweitzer, D.L, R.W. Sassaman, and C.H.
Schallau. 1972. Allowable Cut Effect. J.
For. 70: 415-418.
Schweitzer, D.L., R.W. Sassaman, and C.H.
Schallau. 1973. The Allowable Cut Effect:
A Reply. J. For. 71: 227.
Sewell, W.R.D., J. Davis, A.D. Scott, and D.W.
Ross. 1965. Guide to Benefit-Cost Analysis~
Resources for Tomorrow Special Report,
Queens Printer.
Sumner, M.T. 1980. Benefit-Cost Analysis in
Canadian Practice. Canadian Public Policy
6: 389-393.
Sumner, M.T. 1980. Conlments on the Public
Sector Discount Rate: Response to Jenkins.
Canadian Public Policy 6: 648-650.
Teeguarden, D.E. 1973. The Allowable Cut
Effect: A Comnlent. J. For. 71: 224-226.
13
Weisbrod, B.A. 1968. Inconle Redistribution Ef-
fects and Benefit-Cost Analysis. in Prob-
lems in Public Expenditure Analysis.
Brookings Instil., Washington, I).C.
Table 1. Average real price for Douglas-fir on the Vancouver Log
Market (1981 dollars per cubic nletre)
Year Grade 1 Grade 2 Grade 3 All Grades
1978 78.44 62.07 35.37 43.72
1979 107.13 82.91 54.77 63.90
1980 107.94 80.99 42.80 53.75
1981 104.52 69.86 33.24 46.06
1982 100.86 58.58 26.28 42.20
Average 99.78 70.88 38.49 50.10
Table 2. The Benefits of Inlproved Management
Backlog
Reforestation
Juvenile Spacing/
Fertilization
Timber Output Without the Project(m3
) 0 750
Tinlber Output With the Project(m3
) 750 945
Increnlental Production (m3
) 750 195
Value of Output Without the Project 0 37 575
(1981 dollars)
Value of Output With the Project 53 160 66982
(1981 dollars)
National Income Benefits 53 160 29407
(1981 dollars)
Table 3.
14
Direct Costs and Time Flow of SilvicuJtural Investment (1981 dollars per
h ctare)
Year Description
Backlog Reforestation
Cost Element
0 Site rehabilitation Labour 254
Machine rental 1016
Total 1270
Planting Labor 203
Seedlings 250
Total 453
4 Brushing and Weedinga Labor 331
Total 331
Spacing/Fertilization
0 Juvenile Spacing/Fertilization Labor 969
Helicopter rental 211
Total 1180
a In some cases, brushing and weeding is unnecessary on planted land, while in other cases it is required a
number of times prior to the seedlings reaching a free-to-grow stage. One treatment at year 4 is intended to
represent an average requirement.
Table 4. Present Discounted Value of Benefits and Costs of Silviculture Investment
(1981 dollars)
Discount Gross Direct Associated Net Benefit-Cost
Rate Benefit Costs Costs Benefits Ratio
Backlog Reforestation
5(~h 3631 1972 820 839 1.30
6(Yl) 2157 1959 487 -289 0.88
7(% 1287 1946 290 -949 0.58
10%) 281 1906 63 -1688 0.14
Juvenile Spacing/Fertilization
5% 3435 1180 364 1891 2.22
6<Yo 2264 1180 240 844 1.59
7% 1498 1180 156 162 1.12
100;0 444 1180 47 -783 0.36
15
Table 5. Present Discounted Value of Benefits and Costs of Silviculture In vestnlenl
Assuming a 1<% Per Annunl Increase in Real Prices (1981 dollars)
Discount Gross Direct Associated Net Benefit-Cost
Rate Benefit Costs Costs Benefits Ratio
Backlog Reforestation
5<% 6277 1972 820 3485 2.25
6<% 3728 1959 487 1282 1.52
7%
2224 1946 290 12 1.01
10<% 486 1906 63 -1483 0.25
Juvenile Spacing/Fertilization
5<Yl) 5323 1180 364 3779 3.45
6<Yl) 3508 1180 240 2088 2.47
7<% 2321 1180 156 985 1.47
8<Yl) 1541 1180 105 256 1.20
10<% 688 1180 47 -539 0.56
Table 6. Present Discounted Value of Benefits and Costs of Silviculture Investnlent
Assunling a 1<Yl) Per Annunl Decrease in Associated Costs (1981 dollars)
Discount Gross Direct Associated Net Benefit-Cost
Rate Benefit Costs Costs Benefits Ratio
Backlog Reforestation
5<Yl) 3631 1972 474 1185 1.48
6<Yl, 2157 1959 28 -81 0.96
7%
1287 1946 168 -827 0.61
10<Y!1 281 1906 37 -1662 0.14
Juvenile Spacing/Fertilization
5<YlI 3435 1180 235 2010 2.43
6<Yl) 2264 1180 155 929 1.70
7<Y!) 1498 1180 103 215 1.17
10<Yl) 444 1180 30 -766 0.37
16
Table 7. Present Discounted Value of Benefits and Costs of Silviculture Investment
Incorporating Shadow Pricinga (1981 dollars)
Discount Gross Direct Associated Net Benefit-Cost
Rate Benefit Costs Costs Benefits Ratio
Backlog Reforestation
5(YI, 3631 1371 820 1440 1.66
6(YlI 2157 1360 487 310 1.17
71Yl, 1287 1347 290 -350 0.79
10(YI, 281 1312 63 -1094 0.20
Juvenile Spacing/Fertilization
5(YlI 3435 666 364 2405 3.33
6l
Yll 2264 666 240 1358 2.50
71Yl, 1498 666 156 676 1.82
8(YI, 995 666 105 224 1.29
101
Yl, 444 666 47 -269 0.62
a Assuming 50% shadow price of labor in year 0 and year 1. Assuming 50% shadow price of capital in year O. In-
termediate inputs are valued at full price.
Table 8. Sumnlary of Net Benefits of Silviculture Investment (1981 dollars)
Technological Shadow Pricing
Discount Base Price Increase Change I<Y!, of
Rate Case I<% Per Annum Per Annum Initial Costs
Backlog Reforestation
5<Y!, 839 3485 1185 1440
6<Y!, -289 1282 -83 310
7<Y!, -949 12 -827 -350
10<Y!, -1688 -1483 -1662 -1094
Juvenile Spacing/Fertilization
5<Y!) 1891 3779 2010 2405
6<Y!) 844 2088 929 1358
7<% 162 985 215 676
8% 256 224
10% -783 -539 -766 -269
17
Appendix 1
Discounting and the discount rate
There are few procedures in the evaluation of
forest investment as important and as controver-
sial as discounting. The economics of silviculture
are significantly affected by the long time horizon
until investment payoff. Even with relatively low
discount rates, the present values of gross bene-
fits are substantially reduced over periods of 40
and 50 years. For this reason, there is considera-
ble distrust of discounting among foresters. Even
when the principle is grudgingly accepted, the
rates used in forest investment analysis are often
low compared to those used in the evaluation of
other government investments as well as the pri-
vate sector. In the foregoing analysis of two hy-
pothetical forestry projects, we have not chosen
this traditional route of least resistance, but have
acknowledged Federal Treasury Board guidelines
and have used rates in the 5 to looA) range. Conse-
quently, an extensive discussion of the rationale
for discounting and for these particular rates is
advisable.
Human beings are impatient: individuals have a
preference for present versus future consump-
tion. Although individuals differ widely in tastes,
income levels and a host of other considerations,
it is possible to conceive of a "social time prefer-
ence" which reflects the weighted average of
such individual preferences. This time preference
is reflected in a "rate" of compensation in terms
of future consumption for the inconvenience of
foregoing present consumption. This "social rate
of time preference" is a natural starting point for
any discussion ofdiscounting.
As society foregoes present consumption (i.e.,
saves), resources can be invested productively so
as to increase future consumption possibilities.
Assuming perfect competition in the economy,
the rate of return generated by the next invest-
ment opportunity, after all savings have been in-
vested, is the "social opportunity cost of capital."
Given a number of restrictions the equilibrium
rate of time preference will equal the opportunity
cost of capital. In this theoretical world, if invest-
ment returns were high relative to savings yields,
entrepreneurs would offer higher returns to
savers, thereby increasing the stock of investable
funds and driving up the rate of time preference.
Further investments would be made, reducing
investment returns and the opportunity cost of
capital as the more productive opportunities
were exhausted. Finally, in equilibrium, savings
yields and the investment returns would be
equal, implying equality of the rate of time
preference and opportunity cost of capital.
In any real economy, rates of return on invest-
ment do not equal savings yields. One obvious
cause of divergence is taxation on the corporate
sector. Taking an example directly from Mishan
(1976, page 127), if 5(~) per annum is required to
attract the necessary volume of savings, and if in-
vestment income is taxed at 50(~h then an invest-
ment must generate a lO(Yc) gross return. There
will be a 50/0 spread between the rate of time
preference and the opportunity cost of capital.
Other causes of divergence include imperfect
capital markets and imperfect knowledge of sav-
ings and investment opportunities. In the real
world the opportunity cost of capital tends to
exceed the social rate of time preference.
This divergence is important for there is a major
debate among economists regarding the appropri-
ate rate for use in the evaluation of public sector
projects. The proponents of the opportunity-cost
approach argue that this is the marginal rate of
return realized in the private sector, and that
government investment will be inherently waste-
full unless it earns an equivalent yield. On the
other hand, the proponents of the time-prefer-
ence approach argue that the use of opportunity
cost will lead to overly myopic decision making;
too little investment will occur to the detriment
of future generations. The argument proceeds
that the social rate of discount expres e society'
preferred allocation of resources between present
and future and is the valid rate for the eVC:lluation
of public investment projects. 1 (Government of
Canada 1976, page 25.)
There is some validity in both arguments. The
opportunity cost of capital is an efficiency mea-
sure of the cost of producti ve resources in the
economy. Its use in public sector evaluations will
ensure maximum returns from any given level of
investment. On the other hand, this given level
of investment may be inadequate for future gen-
erations. Use of a second best discount rate
which integrates the two concepts has been sug-
gested. For example, one generally accepted ap-
proach recognizes that public sector investment
funds can be obtained from different sources.
Specifically, increased personal taxes will reduce
both consumption and savings. It is argued that
the opportunity-cost approach is appropriate for
the portion raised from savings as it displaces pri-
vate investment, while the rate of time prefer-
ence is appropriate for reduced consumption. As
a result, they suggest that a weighted average
rate be used according to the proportion of funds
raised from these two sources.
This source-of-funds approach, and its numerous
variations, have some opponents. The British
Columbia provincial government's guidelines on
benefit-cost analysis reject the argument because
funds can always be invested in the private
sector. Consequently, there is never a rationale
to discount at a lesser rate than the opportunity
cost of capital (Government of British Columbia
1977, page 71). While Mishan (1976, pages
136-140) generally agrees with this reasoning, he
notes the importance of political and institutional
constraints. It may be infeasible to invest the
funds in the private sector and, under these con-
ditions, the source of funds is important. The ap-
propriate discount rate for funds raised through
reduced consumption is indeed the social rate of
time preference. Overall, the compromise posi-
tion is reasonable, and its general use is endorsed
in the Federal Treasury Board guidelines.
Setting aside the debate on the appropriate dis-
I This debate is often clouded by philosophical preferences. The use
of a lower discount rate in the public sector will imply. over time. a
larger public sector capital stock and an increased government pre-
sence in the economy. This is clearly less acceptable to advocates of
free enterprise than to the more liberal and interventionist among
the economics profession.
18
count rate concept, a second element of debate
relates to the specific rate to be used. There are a
large number of different rates of return on in-
vestments in different sectors of the economy
and on different savings vehicles. This is due to
unequal risks, differential effects of corporate
and personal income taxes and a range of other
circumstances. It is not obvious which specific
rate should be used as a measure of either oppor-
tunity costs or social time preference. .
An empirical study by Jenkins (1972) is the most
widely cited analysis of the opportunity cost of
capital. Jenkins employed the financial state-
ments of numerous Canadian industries over the
period 1965-1969 to estimate rates of return on
private investment in the Canadian economy. He
concluded that rates of return ranged from as
high as 15.1% per annum in manufacturing in-
dustries to as low as 2.8% per annum in agricul-
ture. However, he estimated the average overall
rate of return on private investment at 9.5% per
annum. It should be emphasized that even this is
no basis for unanimity on the opportunity cost of
capital. Some analysts, such as Sumner (1980)
and Burgess (1981), have argued that Jenkins
average rate of return on private investment is
too high. Others, such as Mishan (1976) have
argued that the discount rate should reflect only
the highest yielding private investments. Sug-
gested rates range between 7 and 15%.
There is considerably more agreement concern-
ing the social rate of time preference. A study by
Reuber and Wonnacott (1961) estimated the real
rate of return on long-term Government of
Canada bonds at 4.75% per annum. Also, a
recent empirical study by Kula (1984) estimated
the Canadian social rate of time preference at
5.2% per annum on the basis of data over the
period from 1954 to 1976. In summary, a dis-
count rate of about 5% appears to have general
acceptance as the social rate of time preference.
This review of discounting and the discount rate
should emphasize the need for discounting in the
proper evaluation of forest investment activities.
Disappointment at its impact on the economics
of such investments should not lead to a blind
dismissal of discounting as an unworthy and un-
necessary frill in the analysis. Discounting re-
flects a rational desire of human beings for
rewards to result from their sacrifices. This
cannot be dismissed lightly. There is considerable
19
debate among economists on the appropriate
concept as well as the specific rate to be used in
the discounting process. However, the range of
rates between 5 and 10%, used in this analysis, is
not excessively high. Even the most generous
analyst would not support a rate lower than 50/0,
while the upper bound of 10% is relatively low.
There are a number of analysts who would sup-
port a rate of 15% or greater.
Appendix 2
Allowable cut effects
One controversial approach which has been pur-
sued in order to circumvent discount rate prob-
lems is the use of allowable cut effects in the eval-
uation of forest investments. This effect results
from the common forest management goal of
sustainable yield and the calculations made to
attain this target. This often implies that present
harvests are perceived to be restricted by the pre-
sent level of silvicultural investment.
As a specific example., in British Columbia the
annual allowable cut is generally determined by
the Hanzlik formula. In its simplest form., this
can be expressed as:
annual = volunle of mature tinlber + nlean annual
allowable cut no. ofyears in rotation age increnlent of
immature
stands over
the planned
rotation age
This type of calculation is also given the general
force of law in the Provincial Forest Act.
With this framework for cut calculations., a more
immediate impact of silviculture investment is
evident. By increasing the mean annual growth
of immature stands., investment in forest
management can have an impact on the present
level of harvesting. In effect, it appears possible
to reap the benefits accruing from the investment
program gradually over the entire period until
the harvest date. For example., the estimated 750
m 3
at year 55 resulting from the backlog refores-
tation project can be converted to a flow of 13.6
m3
per annum over the 55-year period until har-
vest. Similarly., the 195 m3 resulting from the
spacing/fertilization project can be con verted to
an even flow of 4.4 m3 per annum over the
44-year period until harvest. This shift of benefits
forward in time can have an immense impact on
the economics of silviculture. However., the
validity of the procedure should be explored.
Is it technically feasible to increase harvests over
the period until investment payoff? This
depends fundamentally upon the age structure of
the forest. The allowable cut effect assumes that
sufficient mature forest will be available for har-
vest until the treated stand matures. This is by no
means certain in a forest with age class disconti-
nuities or a general lack of mature forest.
Even if sufficient mature forests are available
over the lifetime of the project, there is another
more fundamental issue involved. If the timber
is available, the failure to harvest this tim ber is
not directly dependent on present forest invest-
ment decisions. The decision not to harvest is
the result of present forest management policies.
The validity of the allowable cut effect therefore
depends upon these policies remaining fixed and
unchanged.
Is present management policy changeable? From
a private com an ers ective it a ears rea-
onabl to tf at allowabl cut poltcy as a Ixed fea-
ture of management. It is not susceptible to
change by independent corporate action. Conse-
quently, the utilization of allowable cut effects in
private forest investment decision making is un-
doubtedly rational. However, from a broader
societal perspective, relevant for government in-
vestment decision making, it is less obvious that
management policies are fixed. The government
can change allowable cut policy at any time and
thereby realize allowable cut benefits in the ab-
sence of forest investment. For this reason, the
validity of allowable cut effects in the evaluation
of government forest investments is question-
able.
If allowable cut effects are considered, the net
benefits of both projects increase very substan-
tially under all discount rates (Table 2.1). Also,
both projects, for the first time, generate positive
net benefits with a 10% discount rate.
However, these results indicate another serious
problem with the use of allowable cut effects in
forest ioy e
framework and other specializ d variation pur-
sued in this paper, the spacing/fertilization pro-
ject was consistently rated the superior invest-
ment. The level of net benefits generated always
exceeded those of the reforestation project. This
situation is reversed when allowable cut effects
are included. The net benefits of the reforestation
project now consistently exceed those of the spac-
ing/fertilization project under all discount rates.
A large element of the benefits from spacing and
fertilization result from quality improvement,
which can only be realized when the treated
stand matures and is harvested. In contrast, the
major impact of the reforestation project is on the
physical quantity of harvest. The allowable cut
effect slants investment decisions to:,ard those
projects with physical impacts. This is a potential-
ly serious distortion if it results in the rejection of
more lucrative alternatives because of lesser im-
pacts on the physical volumes. Other equally per-
verse results often follow from the use of allow-
able cut effects in forest investment evaluation.
Table 2.1. Present Discounted Value of Benefits and Costs of Silviculture Investment
Incorporating Allowable Cut Effects
Discount Gross Direct Associated Net Benefit-Cost
Rate Benefits Costs Costs Benefits Ratio
Backlog Reforestation
5°1t) 13 792 1972 4077 7743 2.28
6<Ycl 11 554 1959 3499 6096 2.12
7% 9898 1946 3050 4902 1.98
10% 6876 1906 2i76 2794 1.68
Juvenile Spacing/Fertilization
50J(} 6214 1180 1252 3782 2.56
6% 4926 1180 1090 2656 2.17
7% 4009 1180 961 1868 1.87
10% 2482 1180 698 604 1.32

More Related Content

What's hot

Knowledge and Innovation for Impact
Knowledge and Innovation for ImpactKnowledge and Innovation for Impact
Knowledge and Innovation for ImpactCIFOR-ICRAF
 
Spatial forest planning on industrial land: A problem in combinatorial optimi...
Spatial forest planning on industrial land: A problem in combinatorial optimi...Spatial forest planning on industrial land: A problem in combinatorial optimi...
Spatial forest planning on industrial land: A problem in combinatorial optimi...KR Walters Consulting Services
 
Beyond Reforestation: Valuing Forest Ecosystem Services
Beyond Reforestation: Valuing Forest Ecosystem ServicesBeyond Reforestation: Valuing Forest Ecosystem Services
Beyond Reforestation: Valuing Forest Ecosystem ServicesCIFOR-ICRAF
 
AEMA-restoration white paper-Final-r 031715
AEMA-restoration white paper-Final-r 031715AEMA-restoration white paper-Final-r 031715
AEMA-restoration white paper-Final-r 031715Megan Maxwell
 
Centre for International Forestry Research: Landscapes and food systems 
Centre for International Forestry Research: Landscapes and food systems  Centre for International Forestry Research: Landscapes and food systems 
Centre for International Forestry Research: Landscapes and food systems  CIFOR-ICRAF
 
Sustainable Water Management by Conjunctive use of Ground and Surface Water o...
Sustainable Water Management by Conjunctive use of Ground and Surface Water o...Sustainable Water Management by Conjunctive use of Ground and Surface Water o...
Sustainable Water Management by Conjunctive use of Ground and Surface Water o...IRJET Journal
 
IJCER (www.ijceronline.com) International Journal of computational Engineerin...
IJCER (www.ijceronline.com) International Journal of computational Engineerin...IJCER (www.ijceronline.com) International Journal of computational Engineerin...
IJCER (www.ijceronline.com) International Journal of computational Engineerin...ijceronline
 
005 Paper 19 Climate 1 Template Airship Papers 2010
005 Paper 19 Climate 1   Template Airship Papers 2010005 Paper 19 Climate 1   Template Airship Papers 2010
005 Paper 19 Climate 1 Template Airship Papers 2010airship70
 

What's hot (14)

Knowledge and Innovation for Impact
Knowledge and Innovation for ImpactKnowledge and Innovation for Impact
Knowledge and Innovation for Impact
 
Spatial forest planning on industrial land: A problem in combinatorial optimi...
Spatial forest planning on industrial land: A problem in combinatorial optimi...Spatial forest planning on industrial land: A problem in combinatorial optimi...
Spatial forest planning on industrial land: A problem in combinatorial optimi...
 
Climate change mitigation and agricultural development scenarios for the high...
Climate change mitigation and agricultural development scenarios for the high...Climate change mitigation and agricultural development scenarios for the high...
Climate change mitigation and agricultural development scenarios for the high...
 
ToR-watershed management
ToR-watershed managementToR-watershed management
ToR-watershed management
 
Beyond Reforestation: Valuing Forest Ecosystem Services
Beyond Reforestation: Valuing Forest Ecosystem ServicesBeyond Reforestation: Valuing Forest Ecosystem Services
Beyond Reforestation: Valuing Forest Ecosystem Services
 
Overcoming Barriers to Adoption
Overcoming Barriers to AdoptionOvercoming Barriers to Adoption
Overcoming Barriers to Adoption
 
AEMA-restoration white paper-Final-r 031715
AEMA-restoration white paper-Final-r 031715AEMA-restoration white paper-Final-r 031715
AEMA-restoration white paper-Final-r 031715
 
Grp5 outlook bot53
Grp5 outlook bot53Grp5 outlook bot53
Grp5 outlook bot53
 
Kenya part 2
Kenya part 2Kenya part 2
Kenya part 2
 
Crop modeling and stress
Crop modeling and stressCrop modeling and stress
Crop modeling and stress
 
Centre for International Forestry Research: Landscapes and food systems 
Centre for International Forestry Research: Landscapes and food systems  Centre for International Forestry Research: Landscapes and food systems 
Centre for International Forestry Research: Landscapes and food systems 
 
Sustainable Water Management by Conjunctive use of Ground and Surface Water o...
Sustainable Water Management by Conjunctive use of Ground and Surface Water o...Sustainable Water Management by Conjunctive use of Ground and Surface Water o...
Sustainable Water Management by Conjunctive use of Ground and Surface Water o...
 
IJCER (www.ijceronline.com) International Journal of computational Engineerin...
IJCER (www.ijceronline.com) International Journal of computational Engineerin...IJCER (www.ijceronline.com) International Journal of computational Engineerin...
IJCER (www.ijceronline.com) International Journal of computational Engineerin...
 
005 Paper 19 Climate 1 Template Airship Papers 2010
005 Paper 19 Climate 1   Template Airship Papers 2010005 Paper 19 Climate 1   Template Airship Papers 2010
005 Paper 19 Climate 1 Template Airship Papers 2010
 

Viewers also liked

Monster Design Co. - Agency Profile
Monster Design Co. - Agency ProfileMonster Design Co. - Agency Profile
Monster Design Co. - Agency ProfileTom Beauchamp
 
Priyan lssn pln
Priyan lssn plnPriyan lssn pln
Priyan lssn plnpriya raj
 
amr english C.V3
amr english C.V3amr english C.V3
amr english C.V3Amr Ahmad
 
Online Assignment
Online AssignmentOnline Assignment
Online Assignmentanila299
 
Caracteristici curiermanager
Caracteristici curiermanagerCaracteristici curiermanager
Caracteristici curiermanagercuriermanager
 
Daftar alat peraga sd dak tahun 2015 asaka prima
Daftar alat peraga sd dak tahun 2015 asaka primaDaftar alat peraga sd dak tahun 2015 asaka prima
Daftar alat peraga sd dak tahun 2015 asaka primaRedis Manik
 
Resume_NINOOP CP
Resume_NINOOP CPResume_NINOOP CP
Resume_NINOOP CPNINOOP CP
 
Seattle Tech Forum - Cold Call vs Warm Lead
Seattle Tech Forum - Cold Call vs Warm LeadSeattle Tech Forum - Cold Call vs Warm Lead
Seattle Tech Forum - Cold Call vs Warm LeadMatthewDykstra
 

Viewers also liked (10)

Monster Design Co. - Agency Profile
Monster Design Co. - Agency ProfileMonster Design Co. - Agency Profile
Monster Design Co. - Agency Profile
 
Tugas sosiologi susi
Tugas  sosiologi susiTugas  sosiologi susi
Tugas sosiologi susi
 
Priyan lssn pln
Priyan lssn plnPriyan lssn pln
Priyan lssn pln
 
amr english C.V3
amr english C.V3amr english C.V3
amr english C.V3
 
Online assignment new
Online assignment newOnline assignment new
Online assignment new
 
Online Assignment
Online AssignmentOnline Assignment
Online Assignment
 
Caracteristici curiermanager
Caracteristici curiermanagerCaracteristici curiermanager
Caracteristici curiermanager
 
Daftar alat peraga sd dak tahun 2015 asaka prima
Daftar alat peraga sd dak tahun 2015 asaka primaDaftar alat peraga sd dak tahun 2015 asaka prima
Daftar alat peraga sd dak tahun 2015 asaka prima
 
Resume_NINOOP CP
Resume_NINOOP CPResume_NINOOP CP
Resume_NINOOP CP
 
Seattle Tech Forum - Cold Call vs Warm Lead
Seattle Tech Forum - Cold Call vs Warm LeadSeattle Tech Forum - Cold Call vs Warm Lead
Seattle Tech Forum - Cold Call vs Warm Lead
 

Similar to Cba of forestry investment canada en

Carbon Capture and Storage : Implications for Smallholders
Carbon Capture and Storage : Implications for SmallholdersCarbon Capture and Storage : Implications for Smallholders
Carbon Capture and Storage : Implications for SmallholdersAbhishek RadhaKrishnan Nair
 
CRP6: Forests, Trees and Agroforestry: livelihoods, landscapes and governance
CRP6: Forests, Trees and Agroforestry: livelihoods, landscapes and governanceCRP6: Forests, Trees and Agroforestry: livelihoods, landscapes and governance
CRP6: Forests, Trees and Agroforestry: livelihoods, landscapes and governanceWorld Agroforestry (ICRAF)
 
Truly Sustainable Housing in the Green Mountain State
Truly Sustainable Housing in the Green Mountain StateTruly Sustainable Housing in the Green Mountain State
Truly Sustainable Housing in the Green Mountain StateDylan McNeil
 
G-Range: An intermediate complexity model for simulating and forecasting ecos...
G-Range: An intermediate complexity model for simulating and forecasting ecos...G-Range: An intermediate complexity model for simulating and forecasting ecos...
G-Range: An intermediate complexity model for simulating and forecasting ecos...ILRI
 
Renewable resources
Renewable resourcesRenewable resources
Renewable resourcesJarin Aishy
 
Analysis of Costs and Returns of Tree Crops Planting in Tropical Environment
Analysis of Costs and Returns of Tree Crops Planting in Tropical EnvironmentAnalysis of Costs and Returns of Tree Crops Planting in Tropical Environment
Analysis of Costs and Returns of Tree Crops Planting in Tropical EnvironmentBRNSSPublicationHubI
 
Defining, Measuring, and Incentivizing Sustainable Land Use
Defining, Measuring, and Incentivizing Sustainable Land Use Defining, Measuring, and Incentivizing Sustainable Land Use
Defining, Measuring, and Incentivizing Sustainable Land Use Kim Nicholas
 
The Restoring Healthy Forests for Healthy Communities Act: Program Design and...
The Restoring Healthy Forests for Healthy Communities Act: Program Design and...The Restoring Healthy Forests for Healthy Communities Act: Program Design and...
The Restoring Healthy Forests for Healthy Communities Act: Program Design and...Sam Rosen
 
Forest Products Utilization
Forest Products UtilizationForest Products Utilization
Forest Products UtilizationAbiralAcharya1
 
GW Group Technical forestry report astronium Costa Rica
GW Group Technical forestry report astronium Costa Rica GW Group Technical forestry report astronium Costa Rica
GW Group Technical forestry report astronium Costa Rica GW Group
 
Optimal farm planning, efficient management of farmers A Lecture By Mr Alla...
Optimal farm planning, efficient management of farmers  A  Lecture By Mr Alla...Optimal farm planning, efficient management of farmers  A  Lecture By Mr Alla...
Optimal farm planning, efficient management of farmers A Lecture By Mr Alla...Mr.Allah Dad Khan
 
20140815 measuring sustainability_macau
20140815 measuring sustainability_macau20140815 measuring sustainability_macau
20140815 measuring sustainability_macauasianturfgrass
 
Third Party Validation Study Report - Green Pakistan Programme
Third Party Validation Study Report - Green Pakistan ProgrammeThird Party Validation Study Report - Green Pakistan Programme
Third Party Validation Study Report - Green Pakistan ProgrammeIhsan Nadir
 
Diagnostic of how the submitted FREL could be improved to better align with ...
Diagnostic of how the submitted FREL could be  improved to better align with ...Diagnostic of how the submitted FREL could be  improved to better align with ...
Diagnostic of how the submitted FREL could be improved to better align with ...CIFOR-ICRAF
 
C L I Mclimatesolutions W W Fmay2k7
C L I Mclimatesolutions W W Fmay2k7C L I Mclimatesolutions W W Fmay2k7
C L I Mclimatesolutions W W Fmay2k7Psdmn Phil
 

Similar to Cba of forestry investment canada en (20)

Building a Framework for Better Biodiversity Management, Australia
Building a Framework for Better Biodiversity Management, AustraliaBuilding a Framework for Better Biodiversity Management, Australia
Building a Framework for Better Biodiversity Management, Australia
 
Carbon Capture and Storage : Implications for Smallholders
Carbon Capture and Storage : Implications for SmallholdersCarbon Capture and Storage : Implications for Smallholders
Carbon Capture and Storage : Implications for Smallholders
 
CRP6: Forests, Trees and Agroforestry: livelihoods, landscapes and governance
CRP6: Forests, Trees and Agroforestry: livelihoods, landscapes and governanceCRP6: Forests, Trees and Agroforestry: livelihoods, landscapes and governance
CRP6: Forests, Trees and Agroforestry: livelihoods, landscapes and governance
 
Truly Sustainable Housing in the Green Mountain State
Truly Sustainable Housing in the Green Mountain StateTruly Sustainable Housing in the Green Mountain State
Truly Sustainable Housing in the Green Mountain State
 
CCAFS Low emissions development (LED) activities funded by USAID
CCAFS Low emissions development (LED) activities funded by USAIDCCAFS Low emissions development (LED) activities funded by USAID
CCAFS Low emissions development (LED) activities funded by USAID
 
G-Range: An intermediate complexity model for simulating and forecasting ecos...
G-Range: An intermediate complexity model for simulating and forecasting ecos...G-Range: An intermediate complexity model for simulating and forecasting ecos...
G-Range: An intermediate complexity model for simulating and forecasting ecos...
 
Renewable resources
Renewable resourcesRenewable resources
Renewable resources
 
Analysis of Costs and Returns of Tree Crops Planting in Tropical Environment
Analysis of Costs and Returns of Tree Crops Planting in Tropical EnvironmentAnalysis of Costs and Returns of Tree Crops Planting in Tropical Environment
Analysis of Costs and Returns of Tree Crops Planting in Tropical Environment
 
Defining, Measuring, and Incentivizing Sustainable Land Use
Defining, Measuring, and Incentivizing Sustainable Land Use Defining, Measuring, and Incentivizing Sustainable Land Use
Defining, Measuring, and Incentivizing Sustainable Land Use
 
The Restoring Healthy Forests for Healthy Communities Act: Program Design and...
The Restoring Healthy Forests for Healthy Communities Act: Program Design and...The Restoring Healthy Forests for Healthy Communities Act: Program Design and...
The Restoring Healthy Forests for Healthy Communities Act: Program Design and...
 
R2 wwf indc_brief
R2 wwf indc_briefR2 wwf indc_brief
R2 wwf indc_brief
 
Forest Products Utilization
Forest Products UtilizationForest Products Utilization
Forest Products Utilization
 
GW Group Technical forestry report astronium Costa Rica
GW Group Technical forestry report astronium Costa Rica GW Group Technical forestry report astronium Costa Rica
GW Group Technical forestry report astronium Costa Rica
 
a-i3959e
a-i3959ea-i3959e
a-i3959e
 
Optimal farm planning, efficient management of farmers A Lecture By Mr Alla...
Optimal farm planning, efficient management of farmers  A  Lecture By Mr Alla...Optimal farm planning, efficient management of farmers  A  Lecture By Mr Alla...
Optimal farm planning, efficient management of farmers A Lecture By Mr Alla...
 
20140815 measuring sustainability_macau
20140815 measuring sustainability_macau20140815 measuring sustainability_macau
20140815 measuring sustainability_macau
 
case of the UK.pdf
case of the UK.pdfcase of the UK.pdf
case of the UK.pdf
 
Third Party Validation Study Report - Green Pakistan Programme
Third Party Validation Study Report - Green Pakistan ProgrammeThird Party Validation Study Report - Green Pakistan Programme
Third Party Validation Study Report - Green Pakistan Programme
 
Diagnostic of how the submitted FREL could be improved to better align with ...
Diagnostic of how the submitted FREL could be  improved to better align with ...Diagnostic of how the submitted FREL could be  improved to better align with ...
Diagnostic of how the submitted FREL could be improved to better align with ...
 
C L I Mclimatesolutions W W Fmay2k7
C L I Mclimatesolutions W W Fmay2k7C L I Mclimatesolutions W W Fmay2k7
C L I Mclimatesolutions W W Fmay2k7
 

More from tmelnik

Розгляд та реалізація успішних петицій
Розгляд та реалізація успішних петиційРозгляд та реалізація успішних петицій
Розгляд та реалізація успішних петиційtmelnik
 
Presentation 5
Presentation 5Presentation 5
Presentation 5tmelnik
 
Presentation 4
Presentation 4Presentation 4
Presentation 4tmelnik
 
Презентація "Державний ринковий нагляд і контроль нехарчової продукції " №3
Презентація "Державний ринковий нагляд і контроль нехарчової продукції " №3Презентація "Державний ринковий нагляд і контроль нехарчової продукції " №3
Презентація "Державний ринковий нагляд і контроль нехарчової продукції " №3tmelnik
 
Presentation 2
Presentation 2Presentation 2
Presentation 2tmelnik
 
Presentation 1
Presentation 1Presentation 1
Presentation 1tmelnik
 
презентація Usaid
презентація Usaidпрезентація Usaid
презентація Usaidtmelnik
 
Презентація проекту постанови Кабінету Міністрів України «Про визначення сфер...
Презентація проекту постанови Кабінету Міністрів України «Про визначення сфер...Презентація проекту постанови Кабінету Міністрів України «Про визначення сфер...
Презентація проекту постанови Кабінету Міністрів України «Про визначення сфер...tmelnik
 
Формування мережі індустріальних парків в Україні, включених до Реєстру інду...
Формування мережі індустріальних парків в Україні, включених до Реєстру інду...Формування мережі індустріальних парків в Україні, включених до Реєстру інду...
Формування мережі індустріальних парків в Україні, включених до Реєстру інду...tmelnik
 
Створення індустріальних парків на земельних ділянках державної та комуналь...
Створення індустріальних парків на земельних ділянках державної та комуналь...Створення індустріальних парків на земельних ділянках державної та комуналь...
Створення індустріальних парків на земельних ділянках державної та комуналь...tmelnik
 
стан залучення піі в україну
стан залучення піі в українустан залучення піі в україну
стан залучення піі в українуtmelnik
 
укладені угоди дпп
укладені угоди дппукладені угоди дпп
укладені угоди дппtmelnik
 
дпп в україні
дпп в українідпп в україні
дпп в україніtmelnik
 
дорожня карта дпп
дорожня карта дппдорожня карта дпп
дорожня карта дппtmelnik
 
реформи дпп
реформи дппреформи дпп
реформи дппtmelnik
 
норм прав база дпп
норм прав база дппнорм прав база дпп
норм прав база дппtmelnik
 
досвід єс
досвід єсдосвід єс
досвід єсtmelnik
 
переваги дпп
переваги дпппереваги дпп
переваги дппtmelnik
 
ознаки державно приватного партнерства
ознаки державно приватного партнерстваознаки державно приватного партнерства
ознаки державно приватного партнерстваtmelnik
 
сутність дпп
сутність дппсутність дпп
сутність дппtmelnik
 

More from tmelnik (20)

Розгляд та реалізація успішних петицій
Розгляд та реалізація успішних петиційРозгляд та реалізація успішних петицій
Розгляд та реалізація успішних петицій
 
Presentation 5
Presentation 5Presentation 5
Presentation 5
 
Presentation 4
Presentation 4Presentation 4
Presentation 4
 
Презентація "Державний ринковий нагляд і контроль нехарчової продукції " №3
Презентація "Державний ринковий нагляд і контроль нехарчової продукції " №3Презентація "Державний ринковий нагляд і контроль нехарчової продукції " №3
Презентація "Державний ринковий нагляд і контроль нехарчової продукції " №3
 
Presentation 2
Presentation 2Presentation 2
Presentation 2
 
Presentation 1
Presentation 1Presentation 1
Presentation 1
 
презентація Usaid
презентація Usaidпрезентація Usaid
презентація Usaid
 
Презентація проекту постанови Кабінету Міністрів України «Про визначення сфер...
Презентація проекту постанови Кабінету Міністрів України «Про визначення сфер...Презентація проекту постанови Кабінету Міністрів України «Про визначення сфер...
Презентація проекту постанови Кабінету Міністрів України «Про визначення сфер...
 
Формування мережі індустріальних парків в Україні, включених до Реєстру інду...
Формування мережі індустріальних парків в Україні, включених до Реєстру інду...Формування мережі індустріальних парків в Україні, включених до Реєстру інду...
Формування мережі індустріальних парків в Україні, включених до Реєстру інду...
 
Створення індустріальних парків на земельних ділянках державної та комуналь...
Створення індустріальних парків на земельних ділянках державної та комуналь...Створення індустріальних парків на земельних ділянках державної та комуналь...
Створення індустріальних парків на земельних ділянках державної та комуналь...
 
стан залучення піі в україну
стан залучення піі в українустан залучення піі в україну
стан залучення піі в україну
 
укладені угоди дпп
укладені угоди дппукладені угоди дпп
укладені угоди дпп
 
дпп в україні
дпп в українідпп в україні
дпп в україні
 
дорожня карта дпп
дорожня карта дппдорожня карта дпп
дорожня карта дпп
 
реформи дпп
реформи дппреформи дпп
реформи дпп
 
норм прав база дпп
норм прав база дппнорм прав база дпп
норм прав база дпп
 
досвід єс
досвід єсдосвід єс
досвід єс
 
переваги дпп
переваги дпппереваги дпп
переваги дпп
 
ознаки державно приватного партнерства
ознаки державно приватного партнерстваознаки державно приватного партнерства
ознаки державно приватного партнерства
 
сутність дпп
сутність дппсутність дпп
сутність дпп
 

Recently uploaded

Call Girls Rajgurunagar Call Me 7737669865 Budget Friendly No Advance Booking
Call Girls Rajgurunagar Call Me 7737669865 Budget Friendly No Advance BookingCall Girls Rajgurunagar Call Me 7737669865 Budget Friendly No Advance Booking
Call Girls Rajgurunagar Call Me 7737669865 Budget Friendly No Advance Bookingroncy bisnoi
 
Booking open Available Pune Call Girls Talegaon Dabhade 6297143586 Call Hot ...
Booking open Available Pune Call Girls Talegaon Dabhade  6297143586 Call Hot ...Booking open Available Pune Call Girls Talegaon Dabhade  6297143586 Call Hot ...
Booking open Available Pune Call Girls Talegaon Dabhade 6297143586 Call Hot ...Call Girls in Nagpur High Profile
 
VIP Kalyan Call Girls 🌐 9920725232 🌐 Make Your Dreams Come True With Mumbai E...
VIP Kalyan Call Girls 🌐 9920725232 🌐 Make Your Dreams Come True With Mumbai E...VIP Kalyan Call Girls 🌐 9920725232 🌐 Make Your Dreams Come True With Mumbai E...
VIP Kalyan Call Girls 🌐 9920725232 🌐 Make Your Dreams Come True With Mumbai E...roshnidevijkn ( Why You Choose Us? ) Escorts
 
Bandra High Profile Sexy Call Girls,9833754194-Khar Road Speciality Call Girl...
Bandra High Profile Sexy Call Girls,9833754194-Khar Road Speciality Call Girl...Bandra High Profile Sexy Call Girls,9833754194-Khar Road Speciality Call Girl...
Bandra High Profile Sexy Call Girls,9833754194-Khar Road Speciality Call Girl...priyasharma62062
 
Mira Road Awesome 100% Independent Call Girls NUmber-9833754194-Dahisar Inter...
Mira Road Awesome 100% Independent Call Girls NUmber-9833754194-Dahisar Inter...Mira Road Awesome 100% Independent Call Girls NUmber-9833754194-Dahisar Inter...
Mira Road Awesome 100% Independent Call Girls NUmber-9833754194-Dahisar Inter...priyasharma62062
 
VIP Independent Call Girls in Taloja 🌹 9920725232 ( Call Me ) Mumbai Escorts ...
VIP Independent Call Girls in Taloja 🌹 9920725232 ( Call Me ) Mumbai Escorts ...VIP Independent Call Girls in Taloja 🌹 9920725232 ( Call Me ) Mumbai Escorts ...
VIP Independent Call Girls in Taloja 🌹 9920725232 ( Call Me ) Mumbai Escorts ...dipikadinghjn ( Why You Choose Us? ) Escorts
 
Booking open Available Pune Call Girls Wadgaon Sheri 6297143586 Call Hot Ind...
Booking open Available Pune Call Girls Wadgaon Sheri  6297143586 Call Hot Ind...Booking open Available Pune Call Girls Wadgaon Sheri  6297143586 Call Hot Ind...
Booking open Available Pune Call Girls Wadgaon Sheri 6297143586 Call Hot Ind...Call Girls in Nagpur High Profile
 
8377087607, Door Step Call Girls In Kalkaji (Locanto) 24/7 Available
8377087607, Door Step Call Girls In Kalkaji (Locanto) 24/7 Available8377087607, Door Step Call Girls In Kalkaji (Locanto) 24/7 Available
8377087607, Door Step Call Girls In Kalkaji (Locanto) 24/7 Availabledollysharma2066
 
Call Girls Banaswadi Just Call 👗 7737669865 👗 Top Class Call Girl Service Ban...
Call Girls Banaswadi Just Call 👗 7737669865 👗 Top Class Call Girl Service Ban...Call Girls Banaswadi Just Call 👗 7737669865 👗 Top Class Call Girl Service Ban...
Call Girls Banaswadi Just Call 👗 7737669865 👗 Top Class Call Girl Service Ban...amitlee9823
 
Top Rated Pune Call Girls Sinhagad Road ⟟ 6297143586 ⟟ Call Me For Genuine S...
Top Rated  Pune Call Girls Sinhagad Road ⟟ 6297143586 ⟟ Call Me For Genuine S...Top Rated  Pune Call Girls Sinhagad Road ⟟ 6297143586 ⟟ Call Me For Genuine S...
Top Rated Pune Call Girls Sinhagad Road ⟟ 6297143586 ⟟ Call Me For Genuine S...Call Girls in Nagpur High Profile
 
VIP Independent Call Girls in Andheri 🌹 9920725232 ( Call Me ) Mumbai Escorts...
VIP Independent Call Girls in Andheri 🌹 9920725232 ( Call Me ) Mumbai Escorts...VIP Independent Call Girls in Andheri 🌹 9920725232 ( Call Me ) Mumbai Escorts...
VIP Independent Call Girls in Andheri 🌹 9920725232 ( Call Me ) Mumbai Escorts...dipikadinghjn ( Why You Choose Us? ) Escorts
 
(Sexy Sheela) Call Girl Mumbai Call Now 👉9920725232👈 Mumbai Escorts 24x7
(Sexy Sheela) Call Girl Mumbai Call Now 👉9920725232👈 Mumbai Escorts 24x7(Sexy Sheela) Call Girl Mumbai Call Now 👉9920725232👈 Mumbai Escorts 24x7
(Sexy Sheela) Call Girl Mumbai Call Now 👉9920725232👈 Mumbai Escorts 24x7jayawati511
 
Mira Road Memorable Call Grls Number-9833754194-Bhayandar Speciallty Call Gir...
Mira Road Memorable Call Grls Number-9833754194-Bhayandar Speciallty Call Gir...Mira Road Memorable Call Grls Number-9833754194-Bhayandar Speciallty Call Gir...
Mira Road Memorable Call Grls Number-9833754194-Bhayandar Speciallty Call Gir...priyasharma62062
 
Vasai-Virar Fantastic Call Girls-9833754194-Call Girls MUmbai
Vasai-Virar Fantastic Call Girls-9833754194-Call Girls MUmbaiVasai-Virar Fantastic Call Girls-9833754194-Call Girls MUmbai
Vasai-Virar Fantastic Call Girls-9833754194-Call Girls MUmbaipriyasharma62062
 
Diva-Thane European Call Girls Number-9833754194-Diva Busty Professional Call...
Diva-Thane European Call Girls Number-9833754194-Diva Busty Professional Call...Diva-Thane European Call Girls Number-9833754194-Diva Busty Professional Call...
Diva-Thane European Call Girls Number-9833754194-Diva Busty Professional Call...priyasharma62062
 
Top Rated Pune Call Girls Dighi ⟟ 6297143586 ⟟ Call Me For Genuine Sex Servi...
Top Rated  Pune Call Girls Dighi ⟟ 6297143586 ⟟ Call Me For Genuine Sex Servi...Top Rated  Pune Call Girls Dighi ⟟ 6297143586 ⟟ Call Me For Genuine Sex Servi...
Top Rated Pune Call Girls Dighi ⟟ 6297143586 ⟟ Call Me For Genuine Sex Servi...Call Girls in Nagpur High Profile
 
Webinar on E-Invoicing for Fintech Belgium
Webinar on E-Invoicing for Fintech BelgiumWebinar on E-Invoicing for Fintech Belgium
Webinar on E-Invoicing for Fintech BelgiumFinTech Belgium
 

Recently uploaded (20)

Call Girls Rajgurunagar Call Me 7737669865 Budget Friendly No Advance Booking
Call Girls Rajgurunagar Call Me 7737669865 Budget Friendly No Advance BookingCall Girls Rajgurunagar Call Me 7737669865 Budget Friendly No Advance Booking
Call Girls Rajgurunagar Call Me 7737669865 Budget Friendly No Advance Booking
 
(Vedika) Low Rate Call Girls in Pune Call Now 8250077686 Pune Escorts 24x7
(Vedika) Low Rate Call Girls in Pune Call Now 8250077686 Pune Escorts 24x7(Vedika) Low Rate Call Girls in Pune Call Now 8250077686 Pune Escorts 24x7
(Vedika) Low Rate Call Girls in Pune Call Now 8250077686 Pune Escorts 24x7
 
Booking open Available Pune Call Girls Talegaon Dabhade 6297143586 Call Hot ...
Booking open Available Pune Call Girls Talegaon Dabhade  6297143586 Call Hot ...Booking open Available Pune Call Girls Talegaon Dabhade  6297143586 Call Hot ...
Booking open Available Pune Call Girls Talegaon Dabhade 6297143586 Call Hot ...
 
VIP Kalyan Call Girls 🌐 9920725232 🌐 Make Your Dreams Come True With Mumbai E...
VIP Kalyan Call Girls 🌐 9920725232 🌐 Make Your Dreams Come True With Mumbai E...VIP Kalyan Call Girls 🌐 9920725232 🌐 Make Your Dreams Come True With Mumbai E...
VIP Kalyan Call Girls 🌐 9920725232 🌐 Make Your Dreams Come True With Mumbai E...
 
Bandra High Profile Sexy Call Girls,9833754194-Khar Road Speciality Call Girl...
Bandra High Profile Sexy Call Girls,9833754194-Khar Road Speciality Call Girl...Bandra High Profile Sexy Call Girls,9833754194-Khar Road Speciality Call Girl...
Bandra High Profile Sexy Call Girls,9833754194-Khar Road Speciality Call Girl...
 
Call Girls in New Ashok Nagar, (delhi) call me [9953056974] escort service 24X7
Call Girls in New Ashok Nagar, (delhi) call me [9953056974] escort service 24X7Call Girls in New Ashok Nagar, (delhi) call me [9953056974] escort service 24X7
Call Girls in New Ashok Nagar, (delhi) call me [9953056974] escort service 24X7
 
Mira Road Awesome 100% Independent Call Girls NUmber-9833754194-Dahisar Inter...
Mira Road Awesome 100% Independent Call Girls NUmber-9833754194-Dahisar Inter...Mira Road Awesome 100% Independent Call Girls NUmber-9833754194-Dahisar Inter...
Mira Road Awesome 100% Independent Call Girls NUmber-9833754194-Dahisar Inter...
 
VIP Independent Call Girls in Taloja 🌹 9920725232 ( Call Me ) Mumbai Escorts ...
VIP Independent Call Girls in Taloja 🌹 9920725232 ( Call Me ) Mumbai Escorts ...VIP Independent Call Girls in Taloja 🌹 9920725232 ( Call Me ) Mumbai Escorts ...
VIP Independent Call Girls in Taloja 🌹 9920725232 ( Call Me ) Mumbai Escorts ...
 
Booking open Available Pune Call Girls Wadgaon Sheri 6297143586 Call Hot Ind...
Booking open Available Pune Call Girls Wadgaon Sheri  6297143586 Call Hot Ind...Booking open Available Pune Call Girls Wadgaon Sheri  6297143586 Call Hot Ind...
Booking open Available Pune Call Girls Wadgaon Sheri 6297143586 Call Hot Ind...
 
8377087607, Door Step Call Girls In Kalkaji (Locanto) 24/7 Available
8377087607, Door Step Call Girls In Kalkaji (Locanto) 24/7 Available8377087607, Door Step Call Girls In Kalkaji (Locanto) 24/7 Available
8377087607, Door Step Call Girls In Kalkaji (Locanto) 24/7 Available
 
Call Girls Banaswadi Just Call 👗 7737669865 👗 Top Class Call Girl Service Ban...
Call Girls Banaswadi Just Call 👗 7737669865 👗 Top Class Call Girl Service Ban...Call Girls Banaswadi Just Call 👗 7737669865 👗 Top Class Call Girl Service Ban...
Call Girls Banaswadi Just Call 👗 7737669865 👗 Top Class Call Girl Service Ban...
 
Top Rated Pune Call Girls Sinhagad Road ⟟ 6297143586 ⟟ Call Me For Genuine S...
Top Rated  Pune Call Girls Sinhagad Road ⟟ 6297143586 ⟟ Call Me For Genuine S...Top Rated  Pune Call Girls Sinhagad Road ⟟ 6297143586 ⟟ Call Me For Genuine S...
Top Rated Pune Call Girls Sinhagad Road ⟟ 6297143586 ⟟ Call Me For Genuine S...
 
VIP Independent Call Girls in Andheri 🌹 9920725232 ( Call Me ) Mumbai Escorts...
VIP Independent Call Girls in Andheri 🌹 9920725232 ( Call Me ) Mumbai Escorts...VIP Independent Call Girls in Andheri 🌹 9920725232 ( Call Me ) Mumbai Escorts...
VIP Independent Call Girls in Andheri 🌹 9920725232 ( Call Me ) Mumbai Escorts...
 
(Sexy Sheela) Call Girl Mumbai Call Now 👉9920725232👈 Mumbai Escorts 24x7
(Sexy Sheela) Call Girl Mumbai Call Now 👉9920725232👈 Mumbai Escorts 24x7(Sexy Sheela) Call Girl Mumbai Call Now 👉9920725232👈 Mumbai Escorts 24x7
(Sexy Sheela) Call Girl Mumbai Call Now 👉9920725232👈 Mumbai Escorts 24x7
 
Mira Road Memorable Call Grls Number-9833754194-Bhayandar Speciallty Call Gir...
Mira Road Memorable Call Grls Number-9833754194-Bhayandar Speciallty Call Gir...Mira Road Memorable Call Grls Number-9833754194-Bhayandar Speciallty Call Gir...
Mira Road Memorable Call Grls Number-9833754194-Bhayandar Speciallty Call Gir...
 
Vasai-Virar Fantastic Call Girls-9833754194-Call Girls MUmbai
Vasai-Virar Fantastic Call Girls-9833754194-Call Girls MUmbaiVasai-Virar Fantastic Call Girls-9833754194-Call Girls MUmbai
Vasai-Virar Fantastic Call Girls-9833754194-Call Girls MUmbai
 
W.D. Gann Theory Complete Information.pdf
W.D. Gann Theory Complete Information.pdfW.D. Gann Theory Complete Information.pdf
W.D. Gann Theory Complete Information.pdf
 
Diva-Thane European Call Girls Number-9833754194-Diva Busty Professional Call...
Diva-Thane European Call Girls Number-9833754194-Diva Busty Professional Call...Diva-Thane European Call Girls Number-9833754194-Diva Busty Professional Call...
Diva-Thane European Call Girls Number-9833754194-Diva Busty Professional Call...
 
Top Rated Pune Call Girls Dighi ⟟ 6297143586 ⟟ Call Me For Genuine Sex Servi...
Top Rated  Pune Call Girls Dighi ⟟ 6297143586 ⟟ Call Me For Genuine Sex Servi...Top Rated  Pune Call Girls Dighi ⟟ 6297143586 ⟟ Call Me For Genuine Sex Servi...
Top Rated Pune Call Girls Dighi ⟟ 6297143586 ⟟ Call Me For Genuine Sex Servi...
 
Webinar on E-Invoicing for Fintech Belgium
Webinar on E-Invoicing for Fintech BelgiumWebinar on E-Invoicing for Fintech Belgium
Webinar on E-Invoicing for Fintech Belgium
 

Cba of forestry investment canada en

  • 1. 1+ Governmenl 04 Canada Canac;,an FOleSlry se~. Gouvernemenl du Canada Service canad'en des forets Benefit-cost analysis of forestry investment G. Alex Fraser Information Report BC-X-275 PacifiC Forestry Centre
  • 2. Benefit-cost analysis of forestry investment G. Alex Fraser Canadian Forestry Service Pacific Forestry Centre BC-X-275 1985
  • 3. Canadian Forestry Service Pacific Forestry Centre 506 West Burnside Road Victoria, B.C. V8Z IM5 ~J Minister of Supply & Services Canada, 1985 ISSN 0705-3274 ISBN 0-662-14414-7 Cat. No. Fo46-17/275E
  • 4. Abstract This report reviews the development and applica- tion of benefit-cost analysis to forestry invest- ments. By use of examples, it leads the reader through a discussion of measurement of costs and benefits, discounting, and the sensitivity of the method to changes in the underlying assump- tions, and clearly states the limitations of benefit- cost analysis. 3 Resume 11 s'agit d'une etude de relaboration de l'analyse coOts-avantages et de son application aux inves- tissements forestiers. A l'aide d'exemples, l'au- teur explique la methode d'analyse coOts- avantages, les techniques d'actualisation et la degre de sensibilite de la methode ala variation des hypotheses fondamentales. En outre, il in- dique clairement les limites de cette methode d'analyse.
  • 5. 5 Table of Contents Page Abstract/Resume 3 Introduction 6 Description of the projects 6 National income benefits 7 National income costs...................................................... 7 Present discounted values 8 Sensitivity analysis 8 Price trends............................................................. 8 Technology change 9 Shadow pricing........................................................ 9 Limitations and other considerations 10 Summary and conclusions 11 Bibliography 12 Appendix 1 17 Appendix 2 19
  • 6. Introduction In 1981, the federal cabinet endorsed, in princi- ple, a nlajor push to increase timber supplies through intensive forest renewal and manage- nlent. The proposed nlechanism for program delivery was a new series of federal/provincial forest developnlent agreenlents. Negotiations with the provinces began in late 1982 and, at this tinle, all except that with Newfoundland have been signed. At both the negotiation stage and later when final progranl approval is requested, there are many elenlents of choice. Not all projects which can im- prove the yield of the forests can be carried out within a linlited budget, and specific projects or areas of focus for agreenlents nlust be selected. Sinlilarly, Cabinet and Treasury Board cannot ap- prove all developnlent progranls which will inl- prove the well-being of Canadians within a linlit- ed budget. Forest renewal nlust conlpete with pri- orities in other resource sectors as well as with social policy. There is a need to choose between alternatives and to set levels of funding and effort. In this type of selection process, benefit-cost analysis is a potentially powerful tool. It is a sys- tenlatic nleans of identifying and evaluating the relatiye nlerits of alternative in vestnlent oppor- tunities. In spite of this, little use has been nlade of benefit-cost analysis in forest investnlent deci- sion nlaking. This reluctance to use benefit-cost analysis stenlS partly fronl confusion regarding procedure. Bene- fit-cost analysis is conlplex and there is considera- ble debate on a nunlber of inlportant aspects of the analysis. There is uncertainty regarding as- sunlptions, and inconsistency and sometinles errors in practice. Although the Federal Treasury Board recognized these problenls and has pronloted consistency through published guide- lines, confusion renlains in areas such as forest renewal and nlanagenlent. The main intent of this paper is to illustrate proper benefit-cost methodology applied to a forest investment decision. Specifically, two hy- pothetical forest renewal and management pro- jects are analyzed. Many of the numbers used in this analysis are rough approximations. Rather 6 than the specific results, the topic of importance here is the deriviation of an appropriate frame- work for analysis and the illustration of the in- formation requirements. A heavy emphasis is placed on sensitivity analysis in order to identify the key factors which influence the results and to determine the circumstances under which as- sumptions can be validly varied. Also, the limita- tions of the efficiency analysis are considered, and alternative ways of incorporating non- efficiency project impacts are explored. Description of the projects The area subject to the two silvicultural treat- nlents is assumed to be one hectare in both cases. Also, the land in both cases is assumed to be located in the Vancouver Forest Region and the grade of land is Site I (the highest classification in the B.C. Ministry of Forests inventory of forest land). In effect, it is the nlost productive forest land in the province. In the first case, due to a failure to replant after initial harvesting, the site has been invaded and covered by noncommercial brush. In the second case, a dense stand of juvenile Douglas-fir aged 11 years has become es- tablished on the site. The first hypothetical silviculture project is a reforestation project involving several distinct steps. First, the present noncommercial cover must be removed and destroyed without harming the soils. Second, within one year of this site rehabilitation, planting takes place. Finally, four years after planting, brushing and weeding are re- quired to remove the resurgence of undesirable competitive brush growth. Each different step in the project varies in the mix of capital and labor used. For example, site rehabilitation is capital intensive, requiring the use of specialized, expen- sive equipment, whereas planting is labor inten- sive. Brushing and weeding can be done either manually or chemically and the labor intensity of the operation depends upon choice. The second hypothetical silviculture project in- volves an integrated progranl of juvenile spacing and fertilization. Spacing involves the selection of superior trees and the removal of the less valuable trees, while fertilization accelerates growth. An integrated program is evaluated be-
  • 7. cause fertilization and spacing are complemen- tary, i.e., their joint impact is greater than the sum of their separate impacts. Like the reforesta- tion project, the mix of capital and labor varies with the project phase. While spacing is largely a labor-intensive operation, fertilization is largely capital-intensive and requires a helicopter deliv- ery system. National income benefits The national income benefit of a project is the value of the goods and services produced over and above that which would exist without the project. In the first project, without silviculture, the commercial productivity of the land would be zero. Since the area has been invaded by brush, the establishment of a commercial stand of timber on the site without investment is improba- ble. Consequently, the benefits amount to the full value of the commercial timber harvest from the site. This, in turn, depends on the age at har- vest and the species planted. It is assumed that Douglas-fir was the species chosen for planting on the basis of the relative productivity of the land, and that age 55 is the selected harvest age. The expected harvest from a planted class 1 site in the Vancouver Forest region is 750 m3/ha at age 551 . The volume benefit from a juvenile spacing and fertilization project is the increment to the ex- pected harvest. Based on studies of the relative impact of these activities, the expected total yield would increase by 195 m 3/ha at age 55. The ex- pected total yield of the site after juvenile spacing and fertilization is 945 m3 /hal . The value of the harvest is affected by the quality of output. As outlined in Table 1, the Vancouver log market differentiates three grades of Douglas- fir with five-year average prices (1981 dollars) ranging from $38/m3 for grade #3 to $100/m3 for 1 Since there is no experience with mature planted forests or mature spaced and fertilized stands, the expected harvest volume is not known with precision. There is a wide variety of opinion on the im- pacts of different silvicultural treatments. The figures used in this analysis are tentative and certainly not subject to unanimous agreement. 7 grade # 1. The overall average price for all grades was $50/m3, indicating that the major proportion of the volume sold on the log market was grade # 3. However, silviculture is expected to improve product quality. Both planting and spacing, through control of stand density, can result in larger trees which command premium prices. Fertilization has a similar effect by stimulating tree growth. For these reasons, it is assumed for valuation purposes2 that the harvest from the two hypothetical projects averages grade # 2. On the basis of these assumptions, the national income benefits of the two forest management projects are outlined in Table 2. The benefit of the reforestation project is simply the total value of the eventual harvest from the reforested land. The benefit of the spacing/fertilization project is somewhat different, incorporating two elements. First, the value of the incremental production is relatively straightforward and is equivalent to the reforestation case, However, a second benefit from spacing and fertilization results from in- creased value of the entire harvest from the treat- ed land. To calculate this item, it has been as- sumed that the harvest would have commanded only average prices in the absence of treatment. The $20 difference between this and the grade # 2 average price is the estimated benefit from quality improvement. National income costs The costs of silviculture investment represent the value of real resources displaced from other uses. These costs fall into two distinct categories. The primary or direct costs are those goods and services which are used in the silvicultural pro- jects outlined above. Based on reported average per hectare cost of silvicultural treatment in the Vancouver forest region during 1981-1982, pro- ject costs by category are estimated in Table 3. 2 Log market prices can be used to value project output only if the market is competitive. If monopsonistic elements are present, market prices may be held below a competitive market equilibrium. In this event, the result would be an underestimate of project bene- fits. In effect, benefits are missed further down the processing chain which are also attributable to the silviculture investment. Although there is some question regarding the competitiveness of the Van- couver log market, these prices are assumed to be adequate in the absence ofalternatives.
  • 8. The second elenlent of national inconle cost is the associated cost of harvesting the resource. In valuing the benefits of the projects., the Vancouv- er log nlarket price was used. This represents the value of output after harvesting and delivery to water. The estinlated average cost of harvesting in the Vancouver Forest Region is $11.00/m3 ., while the estinlated transport cost is $0.1 O/knl/ nl~3. Assunling a distance of 50 knl to water., the total associated cost of harvesting and transporta- tion for the reforestation project would be $12 000 (1981)., incurred at year 55 following planting. The associated cost of harvesting and transportation for increnlental production fronl the spacing/fertilization project would be $3120 (1981) incurred 44 years after treatnlent. Present discounted values The benefits and costs of any silviculture invest- nlent are realized over different tinle periods. While the nlajor direct costs are incurred early in the project., the benefits are realized and the asso- ciated costs are incurred nlany years after the ini- tial in vestnlent. Also., there are substantial dif- ferences between projects in the tinle flow of benefits and costs. For exanl pIe., the direct costs of backlog planting are spread over a five-year period early in the project., while the benefits are realized 55 years after the initial investnlent. In the case of the spacing/fertilization project., all direct costs are incurred within one year., while the benefits are realized 44 years later. Society is not indifferent to such variations. Delayed bene- fits are less valuable because they are unavailable for inlnlediate consunlption or reinvestnlent. In benefit-cost analysis., the discount rate is the nleans through which benefits and costs which vary widely in tinling are conlpared. In effect., future benefits and future costs are adjusted downwards to reflect their reduced value. There is considerable debate anlong econonlists on the appropriate concepts as well as the specific rate to be used in the discounting process. The extensive technical literature on this subject is sunlnlarized in Appendix 1. Federal Treasury Board Guidelines suggest that present values be calculated on the basis of a range of discount rates., including 5., 10 and 15(%. In this analysis., calculations are made with a 8 range of rates between 5 and lO(Y() as this is suffi- cient to illustrate the importance of discounting to project evaluation. The net benefits of the backlog reforestation pro- jects are positive only with a 5(~) discount rate (Table 4). The calculations indicate that the in- ternal rate of return on investnlent (i.e.., the dis- count rate which exactly equates benefits and costs) lies sonlewhere between 5 and 6°/<) per annunl. In contrast., the net benefits of the spac- ing/fertilization project remain positive at a 7% discount rate. The internal rate of return on the spacing/fertilization investnlent lies somewhere between 7 and 8(Y() per annum or approxinlately 2(Y!) greater than the return on the reforestation investnlent. At any discount rate., the benefit- cost ratio for the spacing/fertilization project con- sistently exceeds that of the reforestation project3. Sensitivity analysis The analysis to this point has been perfornled in a very elenlentary franlework. There are nunler- ous inlplicit assunlptions which can be changed to reflect current nlarket conditions or possible future industry trends. A nunlber of these possi- ble variations are pursued here in order to test the sensitivity of the results and to explain the conditions under which such variations are valid. a. Price trends Tinlber is beconling increasingly scarce. Both the denland for forest products and the denland for alternative uses of forest land are increasing as world population grows. Sonle current forest land will be alienated fronl forest production in the future. Also., as the renlaining stands of :3 In the example pursued here, the three basic ranking criteria (i.e., Benefit-Cost Ratio, Level of Net Benefits and Internal Rate of Return) result in consistent ranking. The benefit-cost ratio and net benefits from the reforestation project exceed those of the spacing/ fertilization project at all discount rates. Also, the internal rate of return of the spacing/fertilization project is higher. For technical reasons, these three criteria need not result in the same ranking of projects. Consistent ranking sometimes requires an adjustment pro- cedure. In general, the level of net benefits is the preferred ranking criterion in the absence of adjustment.
  • 9. virgin timber are harvested, the future produc- tivity of forest land will be lowered. It is conceiva- ble that future decreases in supply in conjunction with increases in demand will imcrease real prices over the long term. There is undoubtedly some upper limit to such trends beyond which al- ternative materials are used or substitute mate- rials are developed. However, even minor incre- mental price increases can have a major cumula- tive impact over periods in excess of 40 years. A long-term analysis performed by the U.S. Department of Agriculture Forest Service in 1982 (An Analysis of the Timber Situation in the U.S., 1952-2030) estimated a trend increase in real lumber prices of 0.7% per annum from the year 1950 through to the mid 1970s. Also, in their opinion., this probably reflects a lower limit on future real price trends. Indeed, the trend in- crease in lumber prices may already reflect a more rapid increase in log prices. If returns to the factors employed in lumber production remained constant over the period, the increased revenue would be passed down the processing chain with a proportionately greater impact. Table 5 presents the benefits and costs of silvicul- ture investment assuming a 1(~, per annum trend increase in real prices over the period until the timber is harvested. Given this assumption, gross benefits do increase substantially under all discount rates. Net benefits from the reforesta- tion projects are now positive under a 7% dis- count rate while net benefits from the juvenile spacing/fertilization project are now positive under an 8(Yc, discount rate. The internal rate of return on both investments has increased sub- stantially. It is now approximately 7(~, for the reforestation project, and between 8 and 90ft, for the spacing/fertilization project. However", at any given discount rate, the benefit-cost ratio and net benefits for the spacing/fertilization project con- sistently exceed those of the reforestation project. b. Technological change Another factor which can have a major impact over long periods is technological change. Over time, there is a tendency for capital and labor to become more efficient in the production of goods and services. In the context of the two hy- pothetical projects, the major impact of tech- nological change would be to lower the associated costs of harvesting and transporting the timber. 9 Although technological change will undoubtedly also lower the direct costs of intensive silviculture investment, the major expenditures here take place in the near future. Real cost reductions would not be pronounced in the short term. Table 6 presents the benefits and costs of silvicul- ture investment, assuming a 1(~, per annum de- crease in the real associated costs of harvesting and transporting timber. In general, assumptions regarding technological change make very little difference to the results. Net benefits of the refor- estation project change only marginally, and remain positive only with a 50ft, discount rate4• c. Shadow pricing In the cost calculations to this stage, the resources used in silviculture investment have been valued at their full market price. This re- flects an implicit assumption of full employment in the markets for the inputs required. What if there is a recession with extreme unemployment in the forest industry? Alternatively, what if an individual project is located in an area of high unemployment or, in some other way, generates jobs for unemployed people? Under such condi- tions, it may be valid to "shadow price" the resources used in the silviculture projects at below their financial costs. However, a number of practical issues should be addressed before proceeding. The timing of investment activities is an impor- tant consideration. Some reforestation activities such as brushing and weeding will not take place for a number of years. Current market conditions should not be projected too far in the future. If the economy is at a cyclical low, present unem- ployment rates are unlikely to persist. For this reason, shadow pricing, in this illustration, was only applied to the resources used in the first two years of the reforestation project. In effect, it is assumed that the rationale for shadow pricing is a .. The output of the two projects has been valued at Vancouver log market prices, and at the this stage the product is an intermediate input to a sawmill, pulp mill or plywood and veneer operation. Tech- nological change may result in additional cost saving further down the processing chain. In a competitive market situation, the e co t savings would be reflected in higher log market prices. This is an additional and potentially significant benefit from technological change which is not dealt with here.
  • 10. general cyclical downturn in the economy. Caution houJd be exercised in estimating the potential of a project to reduce unemployment; it is unlikely that all of the labor hired and capital used will be currently unemployed. A one-to-one relationship between jobs created and reduction in unemployment occurs only where there is very high unemployment and a relative abun- dance of all required skills and equipment. Even in times of extreme unemployment, shortages can exist for specific skill categories and equip- ment items. Also, unless hiring is strictly con- trolled, there is uncertainty that the individuals employed or equipment used will be drawn from the pool of unemployed labor or capital. Also, what specific shadow value should be at- tached to a particular input? For example, an as- sumption that the shadow price of unemployed labor is zero implicitly attaches a zero value to lei- sure, and this is not strictly true. Similarly, a zero shadow price for capital equipment ignores the deterioration of that equipment through use. Bearing all of this in mind, a shadow value of SOlVO of financial cost was attached to the capital and labor employed in both projects for illustra- tive purposes in this analysis,. Finally, there is the problem of handling inter- mediate inputs such as fuel and the seedlings planted. For example, if two-year-old seedlings were used in the reforestation project, labor and capital market conditions may have substantially changed. Also, labor and capital are a very small element in the price of fuel. For these reasons, it is best that these intermediate inputs be valued at their full financial costs. For the reforestation project, the fuel cost of the initial site rehabilita- tion is assumed to be $250, and an additional $250 is the estimated cost of seedlings for plant- ing. For the spacing/fertilization project, the fuel cost for helicopter delivery of fertilizer is as- sumed to be $150. Shadow pricing does substantially reduce the direct costs of silviculture investment under all discount rates (Table 7). The effects are partic- ularly pronounced with the spacing/fertilization project where direct costs are reduced to less than 60% of their previous levels. The reason for this is the more immediate nature of the invest- ment. While spacing and fertilization take place within one year, reforestation activities extend 10 over a considerable time period. Shadow pricing, on the basis of current labor and capital market conditions, has more leverage on the costs of the spacing/fertilization project. Limitations and other considerations Is the benefit-cost analysis described to this point adequate for decision making? So far, it has dealt only with the efficiency effects of investment in silviculture. This dollars- and-cents orientation of benefit-cost analysis is often criticized, and it is certainly true that the objectives and responsibilities of government extend far beyond mere economic efficiency. For example, equitable distribution of income and improved quality of life are also fundamental social concerns. In addition, there are technical limitations with the efficiency analysis pursued to this point. With respect to technical limitations, certain as- sumptions are implicit within a benefit-cost framework which may not be valid in all circum- stances. As a specific example, studies by the British Columbia Ministry of Forests indicate that the present level of timber harvest cannot be maintained with the present level of silvicultural investment. The potential long-term decline in harvests could adversely effect the province as a whole, and particularly those areas which are almost solely dependent on the forest industry. Within the framework of benefit-cost analysis, there is an implicit assumption of a costless and easy adjustment to such changed levels of economic activity. However, this is unlikely to be the case. In general, long-run decisions are being made to invest in plant and equipment and regarding location of residence, etc., on the as- sumption of future continuity of timber supplies. Given this fact, future timber shortages could impose substantial social and economic costs on future generations of British Columbians. Clear- ly, avoidance, or at least reduction, of these social and economic costs may be a significant benefit of increased silviculture investment. These potential benefits should be recognized. With _respect to non-efficiency objectives of
  • 11. government, the overall program and individual projects within it may serve these to a greater or lesser extent. For example, in the context of the two hypothetical investment projects analyzed, the reforestation project may generate employ- ment for native Indians or some equally disad- vantaged group, while the spacing/fertilization project may have no similar impact. Also, the reforestation project may have more beneficial impacts on the quality of the environment by eliminating an eyesore in a populated area~ To' the extent that these other objectives of govern- . ment are served better by the economically less- efficient project, maximizing social rather than economic efficiency may warrant its selection. There are two general methods of dealing with technical limitations and with non-efficiency ob- jectives in the context of benefit-cost analysis. First, an attempt can be made to integrate these effects within the financial framework. For exam- ple, the economic costs associated with falldown could be estimated. In this case, not only the direct but also the indirect (multiplier) impacts are relevant. In addition, the distribution of im- pacts between private and government sectors is an important consideration. Also, as suggested by Weisbrod (1968), weights can be assigned to the distribution of project benefits. Thus, addi- tional income to a low-income group may be valued more highly than the same income to a high-income group. Finally, attempts can be made to value such nonmarket items as environ- mental quality. The major problem with this ap- proach is the requirement for an explicit valua- tion by the analyst, which may require a large amount of information which is unavailable. Beyond this, however, and regardless of the par- ticular methods used to derive such values, this procedure usurps the decision maker's role. In effect, it pushes benefit-cost analysis beyond its limited objective offacilitating rational choice. A more satisfactory method of handling non- efficiency effects and broader social concerns is simply to document these impacts for parallel presentation with the financial information. In this procedure, the format of benefit-cost analysis is useful for clarifying thinking. Objectives beyond economic efficiency can be verbalized and the extent to which various alternatives con- tribute to their attainment can be investigated. In effect, it encourages a more tightly argued and quantitative approach to the impacts of a project 11 in social and environmental terms. A particularly good illustration of this procedure is given in the planning for Canada's west coast salmon enhancement program. Here, several high-priority objectives were identified including income and employment for both Native Indians and for residents in the less developed regions of B.C. Various measures of effectiveness in attain- ing these objectives were developed. Estimates were then made of the contribution of individual projects, as well as alternative programs, to the achievement of these objectives. All of this infor- mation was then provided in the program analysis (Friedlaender and Fraser 1981). Summary and conclusions This paper has illustrated benefit-cost methodol- ogy applied to two hypothetical silvicultural pro- jects. Table 8 summarizes the net benefits under the initial base case and with the various specified assumptions examined. Under all assumptions, the spacing/fertilization project is the superior in- vestment with net benefits consistently exceed- ing those of the reforestation project. However, no single assumption investigated here is suffi- cient to generate positive net benefits from either project at the 10% discount rate recom- mended by Federal Treasury Board for the evalu- ation of public sector investments. It must be remembered that the numbers used in the analysis are rough approximations and the re- sults should be interpreted with care. However, the assumptions regarding both revenues and costs are relatively generous reflecting invest- ments which are undoubtedly superior to the average forest investment in the province. The two hypothetical projects are assumed to be locat- ed on the best land, involve the most valuable species and are located relatively near processing facilities. In addition, the outcome of the projects has been treated as certain. Realistically, project benefits should be deflated to reflect the risks of loss due to forest fire, insect or disease attack and plantation failure. It is resoundingly clear that the discount rate is of overwhelming importance in determining the financial viability of forest investments. For this
  • 12. reason, both the theoretical determination of the appropriate discount rate and the empirical evi- d nc on it p in valu are discussed in Ap- pendix I. A second appendix is included which in- vestigates allowable cut effects. This is a contro- versial method which has often been used in forest investment analysis in order to circumvent the discount rate problem. The validity of using this method is questionable, but it is included for completeness. The results of the financial analysis underline the importance of other non-efficiency benefits ofsil- vicultural activities. It is likely that these broader social concerns are the primary justification for investment. However, this should not be used as an excuse to ignore the relative efficiency of vari- ous alternatives. Complete information on all of the various benefits of the proposed investments should be presented to decision makers, along with the financial information, for their consider- ation. The choice between various projects and programs remains a basic political decision. How- ever, benefit-cost analysis can facilitate rational choice by ensuring that decision makers know the relative merits of their various options. Bibliography Burgess, D.F. 1981. The Social Discount Rate for Canada: Theory and Evidence. Canadian Public Policy 7: 383-393. Friedlaender, M. and A. Fraser. 1981. Social Im- pacts and Economic Efficiency in Resource Development Planning: The Case of Sal- mon Enhancement in British Columbia, in Tester and Mykes (eds.) Social Impact As- sessment, Detselig Enterprises Ltd., Cal- gary, Alberta. Government of British Columbia. 1977. Guide- lines for Benefit-Cost Analysis. Environ- ment and Land Use Committee Secretariat, Victoria, B.C. Government of Canada. 1976. Benefit Cost Anal- ysis Guide. Treasury Board Secretariat, Ottawa. 12 Gaffney, M.M. 1957. Concepts of FinanaciaI Maturity of Timber and Other Assets. A.E. Info. Series #62, Dept. of Agric. Econom- ics, North Carolina State College, Raleigh, North Carolina. Jenkins, G.P. 1972. The Measurement of Rates of Return and Taxation from Private Capital in Canada. Niskanen et al. (eds.) Benefit- Cost and Policy Analysis, Chicago, Ill. pp. 211-227. Jenkins, G.P. 1980. Discount Rates for Econom- ic Appraisal of Public Sector Expenditures. Canadian Public Policy 6: 549-555. Jenkins, G.P. 1981. The Public Sector Discount Rate for Canada: Some Further Observa- tions.Canadian Public Policy 7: 399-407. Kula, E. 1984. Derivation of Social Time Prefer- ence Rates for the United States and Canada. Q. J. Econ. 49: 873-882. Mishan, E.J. 1976. Elements of Cost-Benefit Analysis George Allen and Unwin Ltd., London, (2nd Edition). Munger, J.A. and J.D. Edwards. 1970. The Splendid but Superficial Contribution of Conventional Economic Analysis to the Management of Public Resources. The Annals of Regional Science, pp. 29-37. Reuber, G.L. and R.J. Wonnacott. 1961. The Cost of Capital in Canada. Resources for the Future, Washington, D.C. Schweitzer, D.L, R.W. Sassaman, and C.H. Schallau. 1972. Allowable Cut Effect. J. For. 70: 415-418. Schweitzer, D.L., R.W. Sassaman, and C.H. Schallau. 1973. The Allowable Cut Effect: A Reply. J. For. 71: 227. Sewell, W.R.D., J. Davis, A.D. Scott, and D.W. Ross. 1965. Guide to Benefit-Cost Analysis~ Resources for Tomorrow Special Report, Queens Printer. Sumner, M.T. 1980. Benefit-Cost Analysis in Canadian Practice. Canadian Public Policy 6: 389-393.
  • 13. Sumner, M.T. 1980. Conlments on the Public Sector Discount Rate: Response to Jenkins. Canadian Public Policy 6: 648-650. Teeguarden, D.E. 1973. The Allowable Cut Effect: A Comnlent. J. For. 71: 224-226. 13 Weisbrod, B.A. 1968. Inconle Redistribution Ef- fects and Benefit-Cost Analysis. in Prob- lems in Public Expenditure Analysis. Brookings Instil., Washington, I).C. Table 1. Average real price for Douglas-fir on the Vancouver Log Market (1981 dollars per cubic nletre) Year Grade 1 Grade 2 Grade 3 All Grades 1978 78.44 62.07 35.37 43.72 1979 107.13 82.91 54.77 63.90 1980 107.94 80.99 42.80 53.75 1981 104.52 69.86 33.24 46.06 1982 100.86 58.58 26.28 42.20 Average 99.78 70.88 38.49 50.10 Table 2. The Benefits of Inlproved Management Backlog Reforestation Juvenile Spacing/ Fertilization Timber Output Without the Project(m3 ) 0 750 Tinlber Output With the Project(m3 ) 750 945 Increnlental Production (m3 ) 750 195 Value of Output Without the Project 0 37 575 (1981 dollars) Value of Output With the Project 53 160 66982 (1981 dollars) National Income Benefits 53 160 29407 (1981 dollars)
  • 14. Table 3. 14 Direct Costs and Time Flow of SilvicuJtural Investment (1981 dollars per h ctare) Year Description Backlog Reforestation Cost Element 0 Site rehabilitation Labour 254 Machine rental 1016 Total 1270 Planting Labor 203 Seedlings 250 Total 453 4 Brushing and Weedinga Labor 331 Total 331 Spacing/Fertilization 0 Juvenile Spacing/Fertilization Labor 969 Helicopter rental 211 Total 1180 a In some cases, brushing and weeding is unnecessary on planted land, while in other cases it is required a number of times prior to the seedlings reaching a free-to-grow stage. One treatment at year 4 is intended to represent an average requirement. Table 4. Present Discounted Value of Benefits and Costs of Silviculture Investment (1981 dollars) Discount Gross Direct Associated Net Benefit-Cost Rate Benefit Costs Costs Benefits Ratio Backlog Reforestation 5(~h 3631 1972 820 839 1.30 6(Yl) 2157 1959 487 -289 0.88 7(% 1287 1946 290 -949 0.58 10%) 281 1906 63 -1688 0.14 Juvenile Spacing/Fertilization 5% 3435 1180 364 1891 2.22 6<Yo 2264 1180 240 844 1.59 7% 1498 1180 156 162 1.12 100;0 444 1180 47 -783 0.36
  • 15. 15 Table 5. Present Discounted Value of Benefits and Costs of Silviculture In vestnlenl Assuming a 1<% Per Annunl Increase in Real Prices (1981 dollars) Discount Gross Direct Associated Net Benefit-Cost Rate Benefit Costs Costs Benefits Ratio Backlog Reforestation 5<% 6277 1972 820 3485 2.25 6<% 3728 1959 487 1282 1.52 7% 2224 1946 290 12 1.01 10<% 486 1906 63 -1483 0.25 Juvenile Spacing/Fertilization 5<Yl) 5323 1180 364 3779 3.45 6<Yl) 3508 1180 240 2088 2.47 7<% 2321 1180 156 985 1.47 8<Yl) 1541 1180 105 256 1.20 10<% 688 1180 47 -539 0.56 Table 6. Present Discounted Value of Benefits and Costs of Silviculture Investnlent Assunling a 1<Yl) Per Annunl Decrease in Associated Costs (1981 dollars) Discount Gross Direct Associated Net Benefit-Cost Rate Benefit Costs Costs Benefits Ratio Backlog Reforestation 5<Yl) 3631 1972 474 1185 1.48 6<Yl, 2157 1959 28 -81 0.96 7% 1287 1946 168 -827 0.61 10<Y!1 281 1906 37 -1662 0.14 Juvenile Spacing/Fertilization 5<YlI 3435 1180 235 2010 2.43 6<Yl) 2264 1180 155 929 1.70 7<Y!) 1498 1180 103 215 1.17 10<Yl) 444 1180 30 -766 0.37
  • 16. 16 Table 7. Present Discounted Value of Benefits and Costs of Silviculture Investment Incorporating Shadow Pricinga (1981 dollars) Discount Gross Direct Associated Net Benefit-Cost Rate Benefit Costs Costs Benefits Ratio Backlog Reforestation 5(YI, 3631 1371 820 1440 1.66 6(YlI 2157 1360 487 310 1.17 71Yl, 1287 1347 290 -350 0.79 10(YI, 281 1312 63 -1094 0.20 Juvenile Spacing/Fertilization 5(YlI 3435 666 364 2405 3.33 6l Yll 2264 666 240 1358 2.50 71Yl, 1498 666 156 676 1.82 8(YI, 995 666 105 224 1.29 101 Yl, 444 666 47 -269 0.62 a Assuming 50% shadow price of labor in year 0 and year 1. Assuming 50% shadow price of capital in year O. In- termediate inputs are valued at full price. Table 8. Sumnlary of Net Benefits of Silviculture Investment (1981 dollars) Technological Shadow Pricing Discount Base Price Increase Change I<Y!, of Rate Case I<% Per Annum Per Annum Initial Costs Backlog Reforestation 5<Y!, 839 3485 1185 1440 6<Y!, -289 1282 -83 310 7<Y!, -949 12 -827 -350 10<Y!, -1688 -1483 -1662 -1094 Juvenile Spacing/Fertilization 5<Y!) 1891 3779 2010 2405 6<Y!) 844 2088 929 1358 7<% 162 985 215 676 8% 256 224 10% -783 -539 -766 -269
  • 17. 17 Appendix 1 Discounting and the discount rate There are few procedures in the evaluation of forest investment as important and as controver- sial as discounting. The economics of silviculture are significantly affected by the long time horizon until investment payoff. Even with relatively low discount rates, the present values of gross bene- fits are substantially reduced over periods of 40 and 50 years. For this reason, there is considera- ble distrust of discounting among foresters. Even when the principle is grudgingly accepted, the rates used in forest investment analysis are often low compared to those used in the evaluation of other government investments as well as the pri- vate sector. In the foregoing analysis of two hy- pothetical forestry projects, we have not chosen this traditional route of least resistance, but have acknowledged Federal Treasury Board guidelines and have used rates in the 5 to looA) range. Conse- quently, an extensive discussion of the rationale for discounting and for these particular rates is advisable. Human beings are impatient: individuals have a preference for present versus future consump- tion. Although individuals differ widely in tastes, income levels and a host of other considerations, it is possible to conceive of a "social time prefer- ence" which reflects the weighted average of such individual preferences. This time preference is reflected in a "rate" of compensation in terms of future consumption for the inconvenience of foregoing present consumption. This "social rate of time preference" is a natural starting point for any discussion ofdiscounting. As society foregoes present consumption (i.e., saves), resources can be invested productively so as to increase future consumption possibilities. Assuming perfect competition in the economy, the rate of return generated by the next invest- ment opportunity, after all savings have been in- vested, is the "social opportunity cost of capital." Given a number of restrictions the equilibrium rate of time preference will equal the opportunity cost of capital. In this theoretical world, if invest- ment returns were high relative to savings yields, entrepreneurs would offer higher returns to savers, thereby increasing the stock of investable funds and driving up the rate of time preference. Further investments would be made, reducing investment returns and the opportunity cost of capital as the more productive opportunities were exhausted. Finally, in equilibrium, savings yields and the investment returns would be equal, implying equality of the rate of time preference and opportunity cost of capital. In any real economy, rates of return on invest- ment do not equal savings yields. One obvious cause of divergence is taxation on the corporate sector. Taking an example directly from Mishan (1976, page 127), if 5(~) per annum is required to attract the necessary volume of savings, and if in- vestment income is taxed at 50(~h then an invest- ment must generate a lO(Yc) gross return. There will be a 50/0 spread between the rate of time preference and the opportunity cost of capital. Other causes of divergence include imperfect capital markets and imperfect knowledge of sav- ings and investment opportunities. In the real world the opportunity cost of capital tends to exceed the social rate of time preference. This divergence is important for there is a major debate among economists regarding the appropri- ate rate for use in the evaluation of public sector projects. The proponents of the opportunity-cost approach argue that this is the marginal rate of return realized in the private sector, and that government investment will be inherently waste- full unless it earns an equivalent yield. On the other hand, the proponents of the time-prefer- ence approach argue that the use of opportunity cost will lead to overly myopic decision making; too little investment will occur to the detriment of future generations. The argument proceeds that the social rate of discount expres e society' preferred allocation of resources between present and future and is the valid rate for the eVC:lluation
  • 18. of public investment projects. 1 (Government of Canada 1976, page 25.) There is some validity in both arguments. The opportunity cost of capital is an efficiency mea- sure of the cost of producti ve resources in the economy. Its use in public sector evaluations will ensure maximum returns from any given level of investment. On the other hand, this given level of investment may be inadequate for future gen- erations. Use of a second best discount rate which integrates the two concepts has been sug- gested. For example, one generally accepted ap- proach recognizes that public sector investment funds can be obtained from different sources. Specifically, increased personal taxes will reduce both consumption and savings. It is argued that the opportunity-cost approach is appropriate for the portion raised from savings as it displaces pri- vate investment, while the rate of time prefer- ence is appropriate for reduced consumption. As a result, they suggest that a weighted average rate be used according to the proportion of funds raised from these two sources. This source-of-funds approach, and its numerous variations, have some opponents. The British Columbia provincial government's guidelines on benefit-cost analysis reject the argument because funds can always be invested in the private sector. Consequently, there is never a rationale to discount at a lesser rate than the opportunity cost of capital (Government of British Columbia 1977, page 71). While Mishan (1976, pages 136-140) generally agrees with this reasoning, he notes the importance of political and institutional constraints. It may be infeasible to invest the funds in the private sector and, under these con- ditions, the source of funds is important. The ap- propriate discount rate for funds raised through reduced consumption is indeed the social rate of time preference. Overall, the compromise posi- tion is reasonable, and its general use is endorsed in the Federal Treasury Board guidelines. Setting aside the debate on the appropriate dis- I This debate is often clouded by philosophical preferences. The use of a lower discount rate in the public sector will imply. over time. a larger public sector capital stock and an increased government pre- sence in the economy. This is clearly less acceptable to advocates of free enterprise than to the more liberal and interventionist among the economics profession. 18 count rate concept, a second element of debate relates to the specific rate to be used. There are a large number of different rates of return on in- vestments in different sectors of the economy and on different savings vehicles. This is due to unequal risks, differential effects of corporate and personal income taxes and a range of other circumstances. It is not obvious which specific rate should be used as a measure of either oppor- tunity costs or social time preference. . An empirical study by Jenkins (1972) is the most widely cited analysis of the opportunity cost of capital. Jenkins employed the financial state- ments of numerous Canadian industries over the period 1965-1969 to estimate rates of return on private investment in the Canadian economy. He concluded that rates of return ranged from as high as 15.1% per annum in manufacturing in- dustries to as low as 2.8% per annum in agricul- ture. However, he estimated the average overall rate of return on private investment at 9.5% per annum. It should be emphasized that even this is no basis for unanimity on the opportunity cost of capital. Some analysts, such as Sumner (1980) and Burgess (1981), have argued that Jenkins average rate of return on private investment is too high. Others, such as Mishan (1976) have argued that the discount rate should reflect only the highest yielding private investments. Sug- gested rates range between 7 and 15%. There is considerably more agreement concern- ing the social rate of time preference. A study by Reuber and Wonnacott (1961) estimated the real rate of return on long-term Government of Canada bonds at 4.75% per annum. Also, a recent empirical study by Kula (1984) estimated the Canadian social rate of time preference at 5.2% per annum on the basis of data over the period from 1954 to 1976. In summary, a dis- count rate of about 5% appears to have general acceptance as the social rate of time preference. This review of discounting and the discount rate should emphasize the need for discounting in the proper evaluation of forest investment activities. Disappointment at its impact on the economics of such investments should not lead to a blind dismissal of discounting as an unworthy and un- necessary frill in the analysis. Discounting re- flects a rational desire of human beings for rewards to result from their sacrifices. This cannot be dismissed lightly. There is considerable
  • 19. 19 debate among economists on the appropriate concept as well as the specific rate to be used in the discounting process. However, the range of rates between 5 and 10%, used in this analysis, is not excessively high. Even the most generous analyst would not support a rate lower than 50/0, while the upper bound of 10% is relatively low. There are a number of analysts who would sup- port a rate of 15% or greater. Appendix 2 Allowable cut effects One controversial approach which has been pur- sued in order to circumvent discount rate prob- lems is the use of allowable cut effects in the eval- uation of forest investments. This effect results from the common forest management goal of sustainable yield and the calculations made to attain this target. This often implies that present harvests are perceived to be restricted by the pre- sent level of silvicultural investment. As a specific example., in British Columbia the annual allowable cut is generally determined by the Hanzlik formula. In its simplest form., this can be expressed as: annual = volunle of mature tinlber + nlean annual allowable cut no. ofyears in rotation age increnlent of immature stands over the planned rotation age This type of calculation is also given the general force of law in the Provincial Forest Act. With this framework for cut calculations., a more immediate impact of silviculture investment is evident. By increasing the mean annual growth of immature stands., investment in forest management can have an impact on the present level of harvesting. In effect, it appears possible to reap the benefits accruing from the investment program gradually over the entire period until the harvest date. For example., the estimated 750 m 3 at year 55 resulting from the backlog refores- tation project can be converted to a flow of 13.6 m3 per annum over the 55-year period until har- vest. Similarly., the 195 m3 resulting from the spacing/fertilization project can be con verted to an even flow of 4.4 m3 per annum over the 44-year period until harvest. This shift of benefits forward in time can have an immense impact on the economics of silviculture. However., the validity of the procedure should be explored. Is it technically feasible to increase harvests over the period until investment payoff? This depends fundamentally upon the age structure of the forest. The allowable cut effect assumes that sufficient mature forest will be available for har- vest until the treated stand matures. This is by no means certain in a forest with age class disconti- nuities or a general lack of mature forest. Even if sufficient mature forests are available over the lifetime of the project, there is another more fundamental issue involved. If the timber is available, the failure to harvest this tim ber is not directly dependent on present forest invest- ment decisions. The decision not to harvest is the result of present forest management policies. The validity of the allowable cut effect therefore depends upon these policies remaining fixed and unchanged.
  • 20. Is present management policy changeable? From a private com an ers ective it a ears rea- onabl to tf at allowabl cut poltcy as a Ixed fea- ture of management. It is not susceptible to change by independent corporate action. Conse- quently, the utilization of allowable cut effects in private forest investment decision making is un- doubtedly rational. However, from a broader societal perspective, relevant for government in- vestment decision making, it is less obvious that management policies are fixed. The government can change allowable cut policy at any time and thereby realize allowable cut benefits in the ab- sence of forest investment. For this reason, the validity of allowable cut effects in the evaluation of government forest investments is question- able. If allowable cut effects are considered, the net benefits of both projects increase very substan- tially under all discount rates (Table 2.1). Also, both projects, for the first time, generate positive net benefits with a 10% discount rate. However, these results indicate another serious problem with the use of allowable cut effects in forest ioy e framework and other specializ d variation pur- sued in this paper, the spacing/fertilization pro- ject was consistently rated the superior invest- ment. The level of net benefits generated always exceeded those of the reforestation project. This situation is reversed when allowable cut effects are included. The net benefits of the reforestation project now consistently exceed those of the spac- ing/fertilization project under all discount rates. A large element of the benefits from spacing and fertilization result from quality improvement, which can only be realized when the treated stand matures and is harvested. In contrast, the major impact of the reforestation project is on the physical quantity of harvest. The allowable cut effect slants investment decisions to:,ard those projects with physical impacts. This is a potential- ly serious distortion if it results in the rejection of more lucrative alternatives because of lesser im- pacts on the physical volumes. Other equally per- verse results often follow from the use of allow- able cut effects in forest investment evaluation. Table 2.1. Present Discounted Value of Benefits and Costs of Silviculture Investment Incorporating Allowable Cut Effects Discount Gross Direct Associated Net Benefit-Cost Rate Benefits Costs Costs Benefits Ratio Backlog Reforestation 5°1t) 13 792 1972 4077 7743 2.28 6<Ycl 11 554 1959 3499 6096 2.12 7% 9898 1946 3050 4902 1.98 10% 6876 1906 2i76 2794 1.68 Juvenile Spacing/Fertilization 50J(} 6214 1180 1252 3782 2.56 6% 4926 1180 1090 2656 2.17 7% 4009 1180 961 1868 1.87 10% 2482 1180 698 604 1.32