SlideShare a Scribd company logo
1 of 83
Rethinking The Current Inflation Target Range In South
Africa
Lumengo Bonga-Bonga, Ntsakeseni Letitia Lebese
The Journal of Developing Areas, Volume 53, Number 2, Spring
2019, pp.
13-27 (Article)
Published by Tennessee State University College of Business
DOI:
For additional information about this article
Access provided by Ebsco Publishing (11 Sep 2018 13:19 GMT)
https://doi.org/10.1353/jda.2019.0018
https://muse.jhu.edu/article/702993
https://doi.org/10.1353/jda.2019.0018
https://muse.jhu.edu/article/702993
T h e J o u r n a l o f D e v e l o p i n g A r e a s
Volume 53 No. 2 Spring
2019
RETHINKING THE CURRENT INFLATION
TARGET RANGE IN SOUTH AFRICA
Lumengo Bonga-Bonga
Ntsakeseni Letitia Lebese
University of Johannesburg, South Africa
ABSTRACT
Critics argue that inflation targeting is not an appropriate
monetary policy framework for
developing countries. They maintain that developing countries
are more susceptible to the negative
effects of external shocks due to the uncertainty perceived by
investors with respect to their
political and economic stability. It is in this line that this paper
assesses whether the 3%-6%
inflation target is the optimal inflation target band in South
Africa. To determine the optimal level
of inflation target in South Africa, this paper follows the
methodology developed by Ball and
Mankiw (2002), which rests on the premise that there is a short
run trade-off between inflation and
unemployment. Ball and Mankiw (2002) show that there exists a
level of unemployment that is
consistent with stable inflation. The unemployment level that
corresponds with a stable inflation is
known as the non-accelerating inflation rate of unemployment
(NAIRU). Thus, this paper uses an
expectations-augmented Phillips curve to estimate a time-
varying NAIRU for South Africa from
1980 to 2015. We use the headline inflation rate and the official
unemployment rate based on the
narrow definition to evaluate the appropriateness of the current
inflation target range. Quarterly
data from 1980 to 2015 sourced from Quantec is used to this
end. The results of the empirical
analysis indicate that, if South Africa were to put in place an
inflation target range based on the
NAIRU, it would have to target an inflation rate that ranges
from 1.4 to 11.5 percent. This range is
different to the official inflation target of 3% to 6% adopted by
the South African Reserve Bank
(SARB). Furthermore, this paper finds that the Phillips curve is
not vertical in South Africa, as
actual inflation does not depend solely on inflation
expectations. The policy implication of the
findings of this paper is that the South African Reserve Bank
should think about revising its current
inflation target, as it is too narrow for an emerging economy.
The current low range of inflation
target could have a negative effect on output and unemployment
in the country. This paper
recommends that the SARB should rely on the realities of the
South African economy rather than
on external concerns when defining the range of inflation target.
JEL Classifications: E52, C13
Keywords: inflation target, NAIRU, unemployment, South
Africa
Corresponding Authors’ Email Addresses: [email protected]
INTRODUCTION
South Africa had double-digit inflation rates from the 1970s to
the early 1990s
(Casteleijn 1999; Rossouw & Padayachee, 2008). In 1994,
following its re-integration
into the international economy, South Africa was subjected to
increased political pressure
to reduce its inflation rate to levels which were commensurate
with its trading partners
(Banerjee, Galioni, Levinsohn, McLaren & Woolard 2008; van
der Merwe 2004;
Padayachee, 2001; Ricci, 2005). Subsequently, the government
introduced inflation
targeting as a monetary policy framework in 2000 (Mboweni
1999) Inflation targeting
policy aimed at stabilising prices in South Africa. A number of
studies support the view
14
that the pursuit of price stability has been successful in
reducing the high inflation rate in
South Africa (National Labour and Economic Development
Institute, 2004 Ricci, 2005).
South Africa managed to achieve single digit inflation rates in
the mid-1990s for the first
time since the 1960s, (Casteleijn, 1999). However, while the
South African Reserve Bank
(SARB) succeeded in reducing inflation, the government failed
to realise the
development objectives as set out in GEAR (National Labour
and Economic
Development Institute, 2004). South Africa experienced a
continued increase in the
unemployment rate from 1980 to 2010, reaching 27% in 2003
(Department of Economic
Development, 2010). In 2010, South Africa was ranked amongst
the top 10 countries in
the world that have high unemployment rates (Department of
Economic Development,
2010). According to McCord and Bhorat (2003), South Africa
has the highest
unemployment rates compared to other emerging countries in
Africa, Asia and Latin
America. The rising unemployment may be attributed to the
change in monetary policy as
international empirical evidence (Akerlof, Dickens, Perry,
Gordon & Mankiw 1996;
Fortin, 2001; Lundborg & Sacklẻn, 2006) indicates that a
change in the inflation rate
from a high level to a low level is associated with perpetual
increases in the
unemployment rate. Some experts reinforce this observation by
noting that at low
inflation rates, the Phillips curve is negatively sloped, implying
a trade-off between
inflation and unemployment (Akerlof et al., 1996; Holden,
2002; Lundborg and Sacklẻn,
2006; Padayachee, 2001). The existence of trade-off means that
reductions in the
inflation rate are directly correlated with increases in the
unemployment rate (Erceg,
2002). Hence, it is essential for a central bank to establish the
correct shape of the Phillips
curve for that particular economy and the consequent dynamics
of the
inflation/unemployment trade-off before deciding, on the one
hand, on the suitable
monetary policy regime to pursue or, on the other, if inflation
targeting is the choice, on
the targeted band.
Critics argue that inflation targeting is not an appropriate
monetary policy
framework for developing countries (Kahn, 2008). They
maintain that developing
countries are more susceptible to the negative effects of
external shocks due to the
uncertainty perceived by investors with respect to their political
and economic stability
(Ricci, 2005). Investor uncertainty and the requirement of a
flexible foreign exchange
market expose small developing economies to negative external
shocks more than it does
big and developed economies (Kahn, 2008; Ricci, 2005). In
addition, some scholars
argue that if the central bank makes the pursuit of price
stabilisation its sole objective,
economic growth and development are inhibited (Kahn, 2008).
However, recent studies
(Arkerlof, Dickens, Perry, Bewley and Blinder, 2000; Ball and
Mankiw, 2002; Fortin,
2001; Lundborg and Sacklẻn, 2006; Hsing, 2009; Fortin, 2001),
on the relationship
between inflation and unemployment indicate that there is a
particular point on a non-
linear Phillips curve where the trade-off is optimised and
central banks should set the
target for inflation at this specific point. Since a number of
authors suggest that inflation
targeting derives its justification from the theory of natural rate
(Bernanke, et al., 1999;
Bernanke, 2003), it is clear that the optimal target for inflation
rate should be set by
taking into account the level of natural rate of unemployment,
which determines the
shape of the Phillips curve. However, the widespread
implementation of low-inflation
targets assumes, without proper verification, the principle of a
vertical long-run Phillips
curve, whereby inflation has no long-run effect on
unemployment. This paper shows that
15
setting inflation targets simply by relying on the idea of vertical
Phillips curve may be
misleading if the actual shape of the Phillips curve is not
vertical.
Given the fact that unemployment has maintained a growing
trend in South
Africa even after the adoption of the inflation targeting policy,
the policy has become
very controversial (Department of Economic Development,
2010; Banerjee, Galioni,
Levinsohn, McLaren & Woolard, 2007; Klasen & Woolard,
2008), this paper aims to
evaluate whether the 3%-6% inflation target band is at a level
that optimised the trade-off
between inflation and unemployment. An optimal inflation ban
should refrain from
generating excess unemployment. The remainder of this paper is
organised as follows: In
Section 2, the literature is reviewed. This is followed by the
discussion of methodology in
Section 3. The estimation of results is detailed in section 4
while in section 5 we provide
the conclusion and policy implications of the research.
LITERATURE REVIEW
Theoretical Discussion
The debate on the relationship between inflation and
unemployment dates back to 1958
when Phillips (1958) found a nonlinear relationship between
unemployment and changes
in wages by conducting empirical tests on data from the United
Kingdom for the period
1861 to 1951. Based on the results of his study, Phillips
concluded that by accepting
some degree of inflation, central banks could maintain lower
rates of unemployment
(Van der Merwe, 2004). Phillips’ conclusion led to major
disagreements among
economists on the existence of a relationship between inflation
and unemployment and,
consequently, the actions that should be taken to address the
trade-off between these
economic indicators (Friedman, 1968; Burger and Marinkov,
2006; Fischer, 1996;
Mankiw, 2001).
Monetary economists argue that the Phillips curve is vertical in
the long run
(Friedman, 1968; Fischer, 1996; Michie, 2003). According this
group of economists, the
trade-off between inflation and unemployment is temporary and
mainly results from the
behaviour of workers as they adjust their wage expectations
following an increase in the
unemployment rate (Hodge, 2002; Friedman, 1968). In the long
run, following the full
incorporation of inflation expectations in wage negotiations;
there is an increase in the
inflation rate and the unemployment rate remains unchanged as
nominal wages adjust
towards their real rate (Hodge, 2002). The unemployment rate
thus returns to its natural
rate and hence, remains stable in the long run (Friedman,
1968:8 and Michie, 2003). A
vertical Phillips curve, as hypothesised by the monetarists,
implies that there is no
permanent relationship between inflation and unemployment.
Post-Keynesian economists
contest this tenet of monetary economists. They are of the view
that workers base their
wages on adaptive expectations; and that a trade-off between
inflation and unemployment
depends on how quickly workers adopt their future inflation
expectations following
disturbances in the economy and on the bargaining power of
employers during wage
negotiations (Holden, 2002; Michie, 2003; Hodge, 2002 and
Michie, 2003). The post-
Keynesian economists maintain that at any unemployment rate,
besides the natural rate of
unemployment, there will be a trade-off between inflation and
unemployment (Michie,
2003). The debate between the Keynesian, monetary and post-
Keynesian economists can
16
only be resolved by evaluating empirical evidence to conclude
whether or not there is a
relationship between inflation and unemployment or whether the
Phillips curve is vertical
or not. The empirical evidence is presented below.
INTERNATIONAL EMPIRICAL EVIDENCE
Existence of a Trade-Off
Empirical evidence supports the existence of a trade-off
between inflation and
unemployment. Research-conducted for European countries
(Holden, 2002); certain
member countries of the Organisation for Economic Corporation
and Development (Ball,
Mankiw & Nordhaus, 1999) as well as for the United States of
America (Karanassou,
Sala & Snower, 2010; Banarjee et al., 2008; Akerlof et al.,
2000)- demonstrates that there
is a trade-off between inflation and unemployment. The trade-
off results from, inter alia,
expectations about future inflation coupled with rigidities in
nominal wages (Akerlof et
al., 1996; Akerlof et al., 2000); regulated and highly unionised
labour markets (Holden,
2002) and shocks to economies (Svenssons, 1999). In their
study, Akerlof et al. (2000)
find that employees’ expectations deviate from rational
behaviour at low inflation levels
and that workers and employers tend to ignore the impact of low
inflation when they
negotiate wages and prices. Akerlof et al. (2000:4) use survey
data based on inflation
expectations of workers and employers to determine the
inflation rate and the
unemployment level, which optimises the trade-off between
inflation and unemployment.
In contrast to models based on rational expectations; Akerlof et
al. (2000) find that the
Phillips curve is not vertical at low inflation levels, and that
there is a trade-off between
inflation and unemployment.
In his study on European countries, Holden (2002) find that
countries with
regulated labour markets, and where the majority of workers are
unionised, face a trade-
off between inflation and unemployment when they target low
inflation rates. This
situation arises because, in unionised labour markets, wages can
only be changed through
mutual consent between employers and workers (Holden, 2002).
Hence, workers and
their labour unions possess bargaining power, which they can
use to prevent employers
from effecting cuts in nominal wages when inflation is low
(Holden, 2002) The inability
of employers to reduce nominal wages unilaterally means that,
in the long run, increases
in nominal wages lead to increases in inflation rate (Holden,
2002).
Determination of an Optimal Inflation Rate
The existence of a trade-off means that there is an optimal
inflation target. An appropriate
inflation target would ideally be close to the optimal inflation
rate on a nonlinear Phillips
curve. Given the presence of a trade-off, studies have been
conducted in certain
developed countries (Akerlof et al., 2000; Fortin, 2001;
Lundborg & Sacklen, 2006;
Maugeri, 2010; Wyplosz, 2000) to evaluate whether the
inflation target is set at a level
that optimises the trade-off between inflation and
unemployment. For example, Fortin
(2001:7) in his analysis of inflation in Canada over the period
1992 to 2002 find that the
inflation target, which is set by the Bank of Canada exhibits a
trade-off between inflation
17
and unemployment. While the Bank of Canada has set an
inflation rate band of 1%-3%,
Fortin (2001) find that an optimal inflation target band for
Canada would be 2%-3%.
In a study of inflation targeting policy in Sweden, Lundborg &
Sacklen (2006)
find that the inflation target of 2 percent, which is pursued by
the European Central Bank,
is not at a level that optimises the trade-off between inflation
and unemployment.
Lundborg & Sacklen (2006) analyse data from 1963 to 2000 and
find that the trade -off
would be optimised if the European Central Bank targeted an
inflation rate of 4 percent.
A similar study was conducted by Maugeri (2010) for Italy for
the period 1960to2003.
Maugeri (2010) finds that the inflation target of 2 percent,
which is pursued by the
European Central Bank, is not optimal for Italy. Maugeri notes
that the inflation rate that
would minimise the trade-off between inflation and
unemployment in Italy is between
15% and 20% (Maugeri, 2010). Making use of survey data on
inflation expectations of
economic agents in regulated and unionised labour markets of
France, Germany, the
Netherlands and Switzerland from 1960 to 1999, Wyplosz
(2000) investigates the
inflation rate that optimises the trade-off of the two variables in
these countries. Wyplosz
finds that the 2 percent inflation target, which is pursued by the
European Central Bank,
results in trade-off between inflation and unemployment, that is,
the low inflation target
leads to the increase in unemployment in these countries. The
results from Wyplosz’s
study (2000) suggest that an optimal inflation rate for France,
Germany, the Netherlands
and Switzerland should be 5 percent. While an optimal inflation
target range should
refrain from generating excess unemployment, Mishkin and
Westelius (2008) suggest
that the higher the uncertainty about the inflation process, the
wider should the target
range be. This is true for emerging market countries, which are
more vulnerable to
external shocks and likely to have more uncertainty about
inflation outcomes.
Empirical Evidence in South Africa
Most of the literature on inflation targeting in South Africa (e.g.
du Plessis and Burger,
2006; Fedderke and Schaling, 2005; Nell, 2002 and Pretorius
and Smal, 1994) indicates
the existence of trade-off, in the short run, between inflation
and unemployment or
between inflation and proxies for demand effects such as
marginal costs and output gaps.
Early studies, which were conducted in the 1960s and 1970s,
find trade-off between
inflation and unemployment (e.g. Gallaway, Koshal and Chapin
(1970); Hume (1971);
Hodge (2002); du Plessis and Burger (2006)) - and between
inflation and output gaps
(e.g. Krogh (1967); Truu (1975); Strydom and Steenkamp
(1967);du Plessis and Burger
(2006)). Recent studies based on output gaps (Pretorius & Smal,
1994; Fedderke &
Schaling, 2005; Nell; 2002) mainly find evidence of trade-off
between inflation and
output gaps. Studies, based on expectations-augmented Phillips
curve of South Africa
(Pretorius and Smal, 1994 and Fedderke and Schaling, 2005),
find that the trade-off
occurs indirectly through labour costs rather than through
prices.
More recent studies (Leshoro, 2012; Phiri, 2010; Gupta and
Uwilingiye, 2008)
demonstrate that the 3%-6% inflation target range limits the
level of economic growth in
South Africa. Leshoro (2012) asserts that an inflation rate
greater than 4 percent has a
negative effect on GDP growth rates. Gupta and Uwilingiye
(2008) assert that a 3% to
6% inflation target range results in a welfare loss, which ranges
from 0.34 percent to 0.67
percent of GDP. Phiri (2010:354) find an inflation threshold of
8 percent and concludes
18
that any inflation rate below and above the threshold will have
an adverse effect on
growth.
Methodology
To determine the optimal level of inflation target in South
Africa, this paper follows the
methodology developed by Ball and Mankiw (2002), which rests
on the premise that
there is a short run trade-off between inflation and
unemployment. Given the existence of
the short run trade-off, Ball and Mankiw (2002) show that there
exists a level of
unemployment that is consistent with stable inflation. The
unemployment level that
corresponds with a stable inflation is known as the non-
accelerating inflation rate of
unemployment (NAIRU) (Gordon, 1997 and Ball & Mankiw,
2002). Thus, this paper
uses an expectations-augmented Phillips curve to estimate a
time-varying NAIRU for
South Africa from 1980 to 2015. The NAIRU is not directly
observable but is estimated
based on variables which are used to determine an expectations-
augmented Phillips curve
(see Staiger, Stock, and Watson, 1997; Boone, Giorno, Meacci,
Rae, Richardson and
Turner, 2003). To determine if the SARB target is set at a level
that optimises the trade-
off between inflation and unemployment, the estimated NAIRU
is used to determine a
stable inflation rate for South Africa. The inflation rate, based
on the estimated NAIRU,
is then compared to the inflation target range that is adopted by
the South African
Reserve Bank. .
The short-run trade-off between inflation and unemployment
can be expressed
as:
Where � represents the inflation rate; � represents the
parameter which represents a constant term in the equation; and
which measures how the inflation rate responds to changes in
the unemployment rate.
Nonetheless, the amended version of the inflation-
unemployment dynamics is
represented as:
Where
e
*
2 shows that the actual inflation depends on the expected
inflation and how U deviates
from
*
U . Supply shocks, such as oil crisis and changes in the
exchange rate, may affect
also the level of inflation.
Ball and Mankiw (2002:118) acknowledge that economic agents
base their
decisions on adaptive expectations
1
. Thus, the expectations-augmented Phillips curve,
which is based on adaptive expectations, is thus presented as
follows:
19
UU
*
1 (3)
Where �−1 represents the inflation rate observed during the
previous period.
The expectations-augmented Phillips curve, as represented by
equation 3 above,
is used as a base to derive an estimate of a time-varying NAIRU
that is used to determine
a stable inflation rate. Ball and Mankiw (2002) show that to
estimate the NAIRU,
Equation 3 should be rewritten as:
*
(4)
becomes:
UU (5)
-hand
side of Equation 5 can be
computed to provide the estimate of
*
U . Ball and Mankiw (2002) suggest the use
of Hodrick-Prescot (HP) filter to obtain
*
U , which represents the longer-term trend and
, the shorter-term supply shock or cyclical movement. The
inflation rate, which
corresponds to the natural rate of unemployment, is estimated
by imputing values for
parameters derived above into Equation 4.
Data and Empirical Results
In this study, we use the headline inflation rate
official unemployment rate
based on the narrow definition ( U ) to evaluate the
appropriateness of the current
inflation target range. Quarterly data from 1980 to 2015 is used
are sourced from Quantec. In order to estimate the NAIRU (
*
U ) we estimate the
U have a unit root, we
have to test if there is a cointegrating relationship between
these variables by making use
of the Engel-Granger cointegration test. It is important to note
that the choice of the
Engle-Granger cointegration over other cointegration
techniques, such as the Johansen
technique, is justified by the fact the Engle-Granger
cointegration technique is robust
even when series are fractionally integrated or depict long
memory (Gonzalo and Lee,
2000). Gonzalo and Lee (2000) show that it is very difficult to
distinguish between series
20
that are fractionally integrated and those that have unit root
(I(1)). By applying the Engle-
Granger cointegration technique, we believe that the results
obtained will be robust even
though the series are fractionally integrated or have long
memory. Moreover, Silvapulle
and Podivinski (2000) indicate that modellers should not be
concerned by the possibility
of small departure from the condition of non-normality when
using cointegration
technique even in finite samples. However, the authors
emphasise that ARCH and
GARCH effects may be more problematic and compromise the
results obtained from a
cointegration technique. The results of the Engle-Granger
cointegration test are reflected
on Table 1. The results show that the null hypothesis of no
U is rejected when inflation is an endogenous variable.
The study adopts the results of the Engle-Granger cointegration
test and
estimated the cointegrating parameter in the relationship
between unemployment and
inflation. The estimation, as per Equation 1, yields a value of
estimated equation is represented as:
TABLE 1. RESULTS OF THE ENGLE-GRANGER
COINTEGRATION TEST
is endogenous
Given the above suggestion by Silvapulle and Podivinski
(2000), we need to make sure
that there is no ARCH effect in the results obtained. Thus, we
perform the
heteroscedasticity test to examine the presence of the ARCH
effect in the obtained
results. Table 2 presents the results of the ARCH test for
heteroscedasticity in the
residual. This test aims to detect the presence of time-varying
volatility or ARCH effect
in the residual. The results presented in Table 2 show that the
null hypothesis of no
ARCH is not rejected with the F-statistics and the observed R-
Squared. This indicates
that the residual is homoscedastic and there is no need to
account for time-varying
volatility in the estimated model.
TABLE 2. HETEROSCEDASTICITY TEST: NULL
HYPOTHESIS OF NO ARCH
F-Statistics 1.707
Probability 0.2001
Obs R-Squared 1.724
Probability Chi-Square 0.1892
Note: The probabilities show the rejection of the null hypothesis
rate of unemployment as per
the procedure described above by using the HP filter. Figure 1
below provides a
diagrammatic representation of South Africa’s NAIRU, together
with the headline
inflation and actual unemployment rate, from 1980 to 2015.
Variable z-statistic Probability
-29.6342 0.0214
U -18.20813 0.2031
21
FIGURE 1. GRAPHICAL REPRESENTATION OF SOUTH
AFRICA'S
ESTIMATED NAIRU, INFLATION AND UNEMPLOYMENT
FROM 1980 TO
2015
Figure 1 shows that the estimated time-varying NAIRU
increases substantially from
single digit figures in the 1980s to double digit figures from the
late 1980s to 2000. From
the year 2000 to 2015, the NAIRU stabilises around 23 to 25
percent. In Kabundi et al.
(2015) and Viegi (2015) we find support for these findings as
both studies show that the
NAIRU stabilises around these rates in South Africa. Figure 1
further shows that the
unemployment rate is below the NAIRU during the period 1994
to 1997. This period
corresponds to increasing economic activities in South Africa.
However, the
unemployment rate in South Africa trended above the NAIRU
during the period 1998-
2000 marking the period of contagion from the Russian and
Latin American financial
crises and during the period post 2008, signifying the effects of
global financial crisis o n
the South African labour market. The trend of unemployment
compared to the NAIRU is
an evidence of the contribution of external shocks to the labour
market and economic
activities in South Africa.
It is clear from Figure 1 that the relationship between inflation
unemployment and NAIRU is far from supporting the evidence
of a vertical Phillips
curve in South Africa, especially after 2004. Figure 1 shows
that deviation of
unemployment rate from NAIRU translates to changes in
inflation rate. For example, in
the period 2004-2008 the unemployment rate in South Africa is
below the NAIRU. This
deviation of unemployment rate from the NAIRU coincides with
the increase in inflation
rate in South Africa. However, during the period of global
financial crisis and the
afterward of the crisis, unemployment soars above the NAIRU
as inflation rate decreases.
This finding indicates thatthe difference between the NAIRU
and unemployment
coincide with the change in inflation in South Africa as per the
theory of the augmented
Phillips curve. This occurrence indicates that actual inflation is
not only influenced by
inflation expectations but also by the deviation of the
unemployment rate from the
NAIRU. This further shows that the Phillips curve is not
vertical in South Africa, as
actual inflation does not depend solely on inflation
expectations. The final step of the
analysis is to obtain estimates of the stable inflation rate that
would minimise the trade-
8
12
16
20
24
28 0
4
8
12
16
20
1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 2005 2010 2015
inflation
unemployment
NAIRU
22
off between inflation and unemployment. The estimates from
Equation 3 yield a rate of
inflation, which ranges from 1.4 percent to 11.5 percent from
2000 to 2015. Figure 2
derived from the South
African NAIRU ( InflaN ).
FIGURE 2. SOUTH AFRICA'S INFLATION RANGE BASED
ON ESTIMATES
OF NATURAL RATE OF UNEMPLOYMENT (INFLAN) AND
THE ACTUAL
INFLATION RATE
0
4
8
12
16
20
1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 2005 2010 2015
Actual inflation InflaN
similar trends, but, in
spite of this, they have different ranges. Moreover, these
results indicate that, if South
Africa were to put in place an inflation target range based on
the NAIRU, it would have
to target an inflation rate that ranges from 1.4 to 11.5 percent.
This range is different to
the official inflation target of 3% to 6% adopted by the South
African Reserve Bank
(SARB). It is a reality that when South Africa implemented
inflation targeting, it chose
an inflation range that coincided with its trading partners rather
than a range that could
optimise the trade-off between unemployment and inflation.
It is clear that monetary policy makers in South Africa are
adopting the inflation
targeting policy on the premise of a vertical Phillips Curve
without sound evaluation of
the domestic context and reality. It is not surprising that
stakeholders such as the trade
unions continue to believe that the South African Reserve Bank
has been too restrictive in
the conduct of monetary policy. Although South Africa’s
trading partners have set
inflation targets at similarly lower rates, these countries have
lower unemployment rate
and NAIRU than South Africa’s which gives them the leverage
to target inflation rates
over narrow bands. Table 3 indicates that a vast majority of
these countries have low and
stable inflation rate interval, and with the exception of Brazil,
all the countries, Thailand,
Peru and Israel target inflation at rates which are slightly below
South Africa’s inflation
target range. It is then difficult to understand why South Africa
has a lower upper bound
inflation rate and a tighter inflation target interval than one of
his important trade partner,
Brazil. A wider inflation target, like the one of Brazil is ideal
for emerging market
economies that are vulnerable to external shocks. A wider
inflation target range could
prevent monetary authorities from frequently reacting to
external shocks. Stringent anti-
inflationary policies might have caused persistent and high
unemployment in South
Africa. Literature shows that a number of emerging market
economies have harmed their
economies from unnecessarily reacting to external shocks. For
example, Mackowiak
(2007) shows that United States (US) monetary policy shocks
affect a larger fraction of
23
the variance in the aggregate price level and aggregate output in
emerging economies
than of the variances in the same variables in the US itself.
Moreover, Kaminsky et al.
(2005) indicate that emerging market economies are
overwhelmingly procyclical in their
conduct of monetary policy and often deepen downturns when
reacting to external
shocks. South African monetary authority may have caused
reduced economic activities
as it responds to the effects of external shocks on the domestic
economy with restrictive
measures. Indeed a number of studies have found that restrictive
monetary policy
reactions often fail to reduce inflation in South Africa (Bonga-
Bonga and Kabundi,
2011). Moreover, in a historical perspective, the 3% to 6%
inflation range adopted by the
SARB is strikingly low, as Figure 1 shows that in the 1980s
when South Africa had one
digit unemployment rate, inflation rate was between 12% and
14%.
TABLE 3. EMERGING MARKETS' SOUTH AFRICA'S
COMPETITORS WHO
ADOPTED INFLATION TARGETING
Country
Inflation
Target range
Unemployment
rate
Chile 2 - 4% 5.90%
Israel 1 -3 % 6.20%
Brazil 1.5 - 8.5% 6.50%
Czech Republic 2 - 4% 7%
Thailand 0.90% 0.80%
Source: Levin, Natal & Piger (2004) and Fraga, Goldfajn &
Minella (2003), World Bank (2015)
Note: unemployment rate is for the period 2006-2010.
CONCLUSIONS
This paper aims to assess whether the SARB 3% to 6% inflation
target range is at a rate
that optimises the trade-off between inflation and
unemployment. Empirical work shows
that countries with low levels of inflation and/or whose Phillips
Curve is vertical (many
of which are developed economies) may adopt low inflation
rate/ ranges targets. Studies
also show that despite South Africa having non-vertical Phillips
Curve, significant high
levels of unemployment, and high-income inequality, its
inflation targeting policy is
modelled around a narrow inflation rate band with a lower upper
bound, unlike countries
at similar level of development such as Brazil. Furthermore,
while South Africa’s
inflation target range compares well with that of other emerging
market countries, the
level of unemployment in South Africa is higher than that of
these emerging market
countries. In this research work, we estimate the stable inflation
rate based on the
expectations-augmented Phillips curve for South Africa. Given
the magnitude of the
computed NAIRU, the estimation results provide an inflation
range that is wider than the
current inflation target range set by the South African Reserve
Bank. The paper
concludes that the current tighter inflation target policy in
South Africa is based on
unsound fundamentals and may have led to some unnecessary
responses by the monetary
authority to apply restrictive measures which in turn have been
detrimental to output
growth and reduced employment, among other things.
The policy implication of this paper is that the South African
Reserve Bank
(SARB) should rethink the current inflation target range of 3%
to 6%. Such a narrow
24
range of inflation target could have a negative effect on output
and unemployment in the
country given that monetary authority may be forced to apply
unnecessary contractionary
monetary policy. Moreover, the findings of this paper that
SARB should broaden the
inflation target range could even suggest that dual targets,
inflation and output targets,
may be appropriate for South Africa. The poor output growth
that South Africa
experiences warrants scrutiny by policymakers.
ENDNOTES
1
Ehlers and Steinbach (2007) show that economic agents in
South Africa make use of adaptive
expectations to a certain extent in forming their expectations of
future inflation.
2
It is important to note that the South African Reserve Bank
(SARB) was targeting CPIX-inflation
from 2000 t0 2008 instead of the headline CPI. In 2008, the
SARB reverted to targeting headline
CPI inflation.
REFERENCES
Arkerlof, GA, Dickens, WT, Perry, GL, Gordon, RJ, Mankiw,
NG (1996) The
macroeconomics of low inflation. Brookings Papers on
Economic Activity 1999: 1 – 76.
Arkerlof, GA, Dickens, WT, Perry, GL, Bewley, TF, Blinder,
AS (2000) Near-
Rational Wage and Price Setting and the Long-Run Phillips
Curve. Brookings Papers on
Economic Activity 2000: 1 – 60.
Ball, L, Mankiw, NG, Nordhaus, WD (1999) Aggregate Demand
and Long-run
Unemployment. Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 1999:
189 – 251.
Ball, L, Mankiw, NG (2002) The NAIRU in theory and
practice. Journal of
Economic Perspectives 16: 115 – 136.
Banerjee, A, Galioni, S, Levinsohn, J, McLaren, Z, Woolard, I
(2007) Why has
unemployment risen in the new South Africa? National Bureau
of Economic Research,
NBER Working Paper Series, Working Paper No. 13167.
Banerjee, A, Galioni, S, Levinsohn, J, McLaren, Z, Woolard, I.
(2008). Why has
unemployment risen in the new South Africa? Economics of
Transition 16: 715 - 740.
Bernanke, BS, Laubach, TS, Mishkin, FS (1999) Inflation
targeting. Princeton
University Press, Princeton
Bernanke, BS (2003) Panel discussion, October 17.
www.federalreserve.
gov/boarddocs/speeches/2003. Accessed 12 Decembre 2015.
Bonga-Bonga, L, Kabundi, A (2011) Monetary policy action and
inflation in
Siuth aFrica: an empirical analysis, African Finance Analysis
13: 25-37.
Boone, L, Giorno, C, Meacci, M., Rae, D, Richardson, P,
Turner, D (2003)
Estimating the structural rate of unemployment for the OECD
countries. OECD
Economic Studies 2002/2: 172 - 211.
Burger, P, Marinkov, M (2006) The South African Phillips
curve: How
applicable is the Gordon model? South African Journal of
Economics 74: 172 – 189.
Casteleijn, AJH (1999) The Viability of Implementing an
Inflation Targeting
Monetary Policy Framework in South Africa. South African
Reserve Bank: Pretoria.
Department of Economic Development (2010). New Growth
Path Framework.
Department of Economic Development: Pretoria Department of
Finance (1996) Growth,
25
Employment and Redistribution: A Macroeconomic Strategy.
Department of Finance:
Pretoria.
Du Plessis, S, Burger, R (2006) A New Keynesian Phillips
Curve for South
Africa. Paper presented at the South African Reserve Bank
Conference: Pretoria.
Ehler, N, Steinbach, R (2007) The formation of inflation
expectations in South
Africa. Working paper no. 3243, South African Reserve Bank.
Erceg, CJ (2002) Choice of an Inflation Target Range in a Small
Open
Economy. AEA Papers and Proceedings 92: 85 – 89.
Fedderke, JW, Schaling, E ( 2005) Modelling Inflation in South
Africa: A
multivariate cointegration analysis. South African Journal of
Economics 73: 79 - 92.
Fischer, S (1996) Why are central banks pursuing long-run price
stability?
Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City: Kansas City.
Fortin, P, (2001) Inflation targeting: the three percent solution.
Policy Matters 2:
1 – 16.
Fraga, A, Goldfajn, I, Minella, A (2003) Inflation targeting in
emerging market
economies. National Bureau of Economic Research, NBER
Working Paper Series,
Working Paper No. 10019.
Friedman, M, (1968) The Role of Monetary Policy. The
American Economic
Review 58:1 - 17.
Gonzalo, J and Lee, TH (2000). On the robustness of
cointegration tests when
series are fractionally integrated. Journal of Applied Statistics,
27(7): 821-827.
Gordon, RJ (1997) The time-varying NAIRU and its
implications for economic
policy. Journal of Economic Perspectives 11:11 – 32.
Gupta, R, Uwilingiye, J (2008). Measuring the Welfare Cost of
Inflation in
South Africa. Economic Research Southern Africa, Working
Paper No. 68.
Hodge, D (2002) Inflation versus unemployment in South
Africa: Is there a
trade-off? South African Journal of Economics 70: 418 – 443.
Holden, S (2002) The costs of price stability – downward
nominal wage rigidity
in Europe. The National Bureau of Economic Research,
Working Paper No. 8865.
Hsing, Y (2009) Estimating the time-varying NAIRU for
Germany and policy
implications. Applied Economic Letters 16:469 – 473.
Kabundi, A, Schaling, E, Some, M (2015) Estimating a Phillips
Curve for South
Africa: A Bounded Random Walk Approach. ERSA working
paper no. 568.
Kahn, B (2008) Challenges of Inflation Targeting for Emerging-
market
Economies: The South African Case. Paper presented for the
South African Reserve Bank
Conference Series on Challenges for monetary policy-makers in
emerging markets,
Pretoria.
Kaminsky, GL, Reinhart, CM, Vegh, CA (2005) When it rains,
it pours:
procyclical capital flow and macroeconomic policies, in NBER
macroeconomic Annual
2004, Vol.19, ed. By Gertler, M. and Rogoff, K., Cambridge:
NBER.
Karanassou, M, Sala, H, Snower, DJ (2010) Phillips curves and
unemployment
dynamics: A critique and holistic perspective. Journal of
Economic Perspectives 24: 1 -
51.
Klasen, S, Woolard, I. (2008) Surviving Unemployment without
State Support:
Unemployment and Household Formation in South Africa.
Journal of African Economies
18: 1 – 51.
26
Leshoro, TLA. (2012) Estimating the inflation threshold for
South Africa.
Economic Research Southern Africa. ERSA, Working Paper
285.
Levin, AT, Natalucci, FM, Piger, JM (2004) The
macroeconomics effects of
inflation targeting. Conference proceeding of the 28
th
annual economic policy conference
on “Inflation Targeting: Prospects and Problems” held in St
Loius. Conducted by the
Federal Reserve Bank of St Louis. St Louis: Federal Reserve
Bank of St Louis.
Lundborg, P, Sacklẻn, H (2006) Low-inflation targeting and
long run
unemployment. The Scandinavian Journal of Economics
108:397 – 418.
Mackowiak, B (2007) External shocks, US monetary policy
shocks and
macroeconomic fluctuations in emerging market. Journal of
monetary economics 54:
2512-2520.
Mankiw, NG (2001) The Inexorable and Mysterious Trade-off
between Inflation
and Unemployment. The Economic Journal 111: C45 – C61.
Maugeri, N (2010) Macroeconomic Implications of Near
Rational Behaviour:
An Application to the Italian Phillips Curve. Unpublished
doctoral thesis. Siena:
Università di Siena.
Mboweni, TT (1999) Inflation targeting in South Africa. The
South African
Journal of Economics 67: 401 - 409.
McCord, A, Bhorat, H (2003). Employment and Labour Market
Trends. In:
Kraak A, Perold, H (eds) Human Resources Development
Review. HSRC Press: Cape
Town
Michie, J (2003) The Institutional Underpinnings of the
Unemployment-Inflation
Relationship: A Review Paper. Human Sciences Research
Council: Pretoria:
Mishkin, FS, Westelius, NJ (2008) Inflation Band Targeting and
Optimal
Inflation Contracts. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 40:
557-582
National Labour and Economic Development Institute (2004).
Highlights of the
current labour market conditions in South Africa. Johannesburg:
National Labour and
Economic Development Institute.
Nell, KS (2002) Is low inflation a precondition for faster
growth? The case of
South Africa. University of Kent, Department of Economics,
Working Paper No. 0011.
Padayachee, V (2001) Central bank transformation in a
globalized world: The
Reserve Bank in post-apartheid South Africa. Journal of
International Development 13:
741 – 765.
Phillips, AW (1958) The Relation between Unemployment and
the Rate of
Change of Money Wage Rates in the United Kingdom, 1861 –
1957. Economica 25:283-
299.
Phiri, A (2010) At what level is inflation least detrimental
towards finance-
growth activity in South Africa? Journal of Sustainable
Development in Africa 12: 354 –
364.
Pretorius, CJ and Smal, MM (1994) A macro-economic
examination of the
price-formation process in the South African economy. The
South African Reserve Bank
Quarterly Bulletin 191: 25 – 36.
Ricci, LA (2005) Bringing inflation under control. In: Nowak,
M, Ricci, LA
(eds) Post-Apartheid South Africa: The First Ten Years.
International Monetary Fund:
Washington.
http://ideas.repec.org/a/mcb/jmoncb/v40y2008i4p557-582.html
http://ideas.repec.org/a/mcb/jmoncb/v40y2008i4p557-582.html
27
Rossouw, J, Padayachee, V (2008) An Analysis of inflation
from a central
banking perspective: The South African experience since 1921.
University of Kwazulu
Natal: School of Development Studies. Working Paper No. 50.
Silvapulle, PS and Podivinsky, JM (2000). The effect of non-
normal
disturbances and conditional heteroskedasticity on multiple
cointegration tests. Journal of
Statistical Computation and Simulation, 65(1-4): 173-189
Staiger, D, Stock, JH, Watson, MW (1997) How Precise are
Estimates of the
Natural Rate of Unemployment? The Journal of Economic
Perspectives 11: 34 – 49.
Svenssons, LEO (1999) Price-level targeting versus inflation
targeting: A free
lunch? Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 31:277 – 295.
Van der Merve, EJ (2004) Inflation targeting in South Africa.
The South African
Reserve Bank Occasional Paper No. 19.
Viegi, N (2015) Labour Market and Monetary Policy in South
Africa. SARB
Working Paper 15/01.
World Bank (2015) World Development Indicators.
http://beta.worldbank.org.
Accessed 27 january 2016.
Wyplosz, C (2000) Do we know how low should inflation be?
Conference
proceeding of the first Central Banking Conference on “Why
Price Stability” held in
Geneva. Conducted by the European Central Bank. Geneva:
Graduate Institute of
International Studies.
http://www.tandfonline.com/doi/abs/10.1080/009496500088119
97#.VSaJJ_mUe50
http://www.tandfonline.com/doi/abs/10.1080/009496500088119
97#.VSaJJ_mUe50
http://beta.worldbank.org/
Copyright of Journal of Developing Areas is the property of
Tennessee State University,
College of Business and its content may not be copied or
emailed to multiple sites or posted
to a listserv without the copyright holder's express written
permission. However, users may
print, download, or email articles for individual use.
Copyright © 2019 The Authors. Published by VGTU Press.
This is an Open Access article distributed under the terms of the
Creative Commons Attribution License
(http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/),
which permits unrestricted use, distribution, and reproduction in
any medium, provided the original author and source are
credited..
To link to this article: https://doi.org/10.3846/btp.2019.01
VERSLAS: TEORIJA IR PRAKTIKA / BUSINESS: THEORY
AND PRACTICE
ISSN 1648-0627 / eISSN 1822-4202
http://btp.press.vgtu.lt
2019 20: 1–10
https://doi.org/10.3846/btp.2019.01
To link to this article: https://doi.org/10.3846/btp.2019.01
Introduction
Post global financial crises (2008) have forced countries
to adopt expansionary and stimulating macroeconomic
policies aiming to reduce unemployment. Some countries,
such as United Kingdom, Germany, and the United States
of America have become successful in lowering the unem-
ployment in their labor markets. However, Spain and Italy
are stuck at high rates of unemployment with rigid labor
markets (Bhattarai 2016). The unemployment could be
stabilized towards their natural rates by stimulating the ag-
gregate demand through fiscal or monetary policies with or
without some increase in price levels (Keynes 1936, Phllips
1958, Benati 2015, Blanchard 2016).
Short-term economic problems, such as inflation and
unemployment are among the most notable macroeco-
nomic problems all the time (Al-zeaud 2014, Arshad 2014,
Bhattarai 2016, Caporale and Škare 2011, Cioran 2014,
Furuoka 2007, Furuoka 2008, Israel 2015, Katria et al.,
2011, Kogid et al. 2011, Mahmood et al. 2013, Okafor et al.
2016, Sa’idu and Muhammad 2015, Ştefan and Bratu 2016,
Thayaparan 2014, Touny 2013, Umaru and Zubairu 2012,
Zaman et al. 2011, Pallis 2006, Benati 2015, Blanchard
2016). The Indonesian government started to focus on
inflation when Indonesia experienced an economic shock
during the transition period (1965–1969). Fortunately, the
Indonesian government managed to control the inflation
rate as Indonesia only had an inflation rate of below 10%
in 1969 (Bank Indonesia 2004). However, the monetary
crisis hit Indonesia again in 1997–1998 that resulted in the
inflation rate of 58.4%. During the post-monetary crisis
period, Indonesia managed to recover that caused the infla-
tion rate to be below two digits. Further, the global financial
crisis hit the global economy in 2008, but the Indonesian
inflation rate remained stable. One of the likely factors of
this condition is the government’ various economic rescue
programs such as the tight money or contractive policy
that was effective in taming the inflation rate. Besides, the
Inflation Targeting Framework that was implemented by
Bank Indonesia (the Indonesian central bank) since July
THE CAUSALITY BETWEEN INFLATION AND
UNEMPLOYMENT:
THE INDONESIAN EVIDENCE
Gatot SASONGKO1, Andrian Dolfriandra HURUTA2
Universitas Kristen Satya Wacana, Salatiga, Indonesia
E-mails: [email protected] (corresponding author);
[email protected]
Received 21 June 2018; accepted 05 September 2018
Abstract. Two closely watched indicators of economic
performance are inflation and unemployment. This study
empirically
analyzes the causality between inflation and unemployment in
Indonesia during 1984 to 2017. The data were gathered from
the Indonesian Central Bureau of Statistics. Methodologically,
this study employed the Granger Causality test and Vector
Autoregression to determine the causality between inflation and
unemployment. The results show that there is a one-way
causality
between inflation and unemployment. The findings imply that
unemployment causes inflation, but not vice versa. Next
inflation
and unemployment are also closely related to other determining
factors, such as season, household income, and the decisions
to attend school or to perform the housekeeping.
Keywords: granger causality, inflation, unemployment, vector
autoregression.
JEL Classification: E600, E610.
http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/
https://doi.org/10.3846/btp.2019.01
https://doi.org/10.3846/btp.2019.01
mailto:[email protected]
mailto:[email protected]
2005 (Bank Indonesia 2017) and the empowerment of the
Regional Inflation Monitoring Team in each local region fa-
cilitated further the inflation control (Sasongko and Huruta
2018).
The high inflation rate in 1965 also caused a high un-
employment rate (read: stagflation). Since 1965, the unem-
ployment rate has increased by 5–6% per year. However,
similar to the inflation rate, the Indonesian government
managed to reduce the unemployment rate to less than 10%
(Bank Indonesia 2004). Every government closely monitor
inflation and unemployment as the two main economic
performance indicators. Statisticians combine inflation and
unemployment data to develop the misery index that aims
to measure the health of an economy. One of the economic
principles is the short-term trade-off between inflation and
unemployment. If fiscal and monetary policymakers in-
crease aggregate demands and economy along the short-run
aggregate demand curve, they can reduce unemployment
temporarily, albeit with an increase in inflation rate. On
the other hand, if monetary and fiscal policymakers reduce
aggregate demands and economy along the short-run aggre-
gate demand curve, they can curb inflation but also increase
unemployment temporarily (Mankiw et al. 2013).
This study aims to investigate the trade-off between in-
flation and unemployment as found by Phllips (1958) espe-
cially on the causality between inflation and unemployment
in Indonesia during 1984 to 2017. It is clear the importance
to recognize the relationship between inflation and unem-
ployment when determining the macroeconomic policies
for an economy. Despite the availability of several studies
that examined the Phillips curve hypothesis, there is still a
shortage of applied studies that investigate this hypothesis
under developing countries where the majority of research
has concentrated on the developed nations. The outcomes
of this study may help policymakers to formulate better
policies that can achieve their objectives of price stability
and full employment in Indonesia.
1. Literature review
Several studies have investigated the relationship between
inflation and unemployment. Al-zeaud (2014) does not find
a causal relationship between inflation and unemployment
in Jordan because the study does not include foreign labor
when measuring the unemployment level, thus inhibiting
the trade-offs between these two variables in the short term.
Further, Furuoka (2008) also does not find the causality
between inflation and unemployment in the Philippines.
The socioeconomic factors such as the output gaps likely
explain the Phillips curve better in the Philippine context.
In Nigeria, Umaru and Zubairu (2012) indicate that there
is no causality between inflation and unemployment. The
findings suggest that the Phillip curve does not apply in
Nigeria and it is necessary to use the unemployment or
inflation theory that is based more on the Nigerian data
and situation.
Besides studies that show no causal relationship between
inflation and unemployment, Caporale and Škare (2011)
demonstrate that there is a one-way causal relationship
between inflation and job opportunities. Their findings,
based on the study on the Organisation for Economic Co-
operation and Development (OECD) countries, thus sug-
gest that inflation affects job opportunities, but not the way
around. This condition recommends policymakers to pay
more attention to the short-term and long-term job and
output growth. In Malaysia, Furuoka (2007) also finds the
one-way causality between inflation and unemployment,
implying that inflation leads to unemployment but not the
way around. The study also demonstrates the cointegration
and causal relationship between inflation and unemploy-
ment in Malaysia. In other words, the results confirm the
existence of the Phillips curve. Still in the same country,
Kogid et al. (2011) document the one-way causality be-
tween inflation and unemployment. Their findings imply
that inflation causes unemployment, but not vice versa. The
results also confirm the trade-off relationship between infla-
tion and unemployment in Malaysia and the government
needs to ensure that the economic policies will facilitate
sustainable economic growth in the future. Using the US
data, Ştefan and Bratu (2016) also find the one-way rela-
tionship between inflation and unemployment, suggesting
that inflation explains unemployment but not vice versa.
Their findings suggest that policymakers should develop
programs that reduce unemployment such as productive
labor projects while at the same time also control inflation.
Besides, the programs should focus on replacing foreign
labors with local labors and on ensuring that the aggregate
demands reach the optimal unemployment and inflation
levels that will eventually support the long-term economic
growth. The Pakistani study of Mahmood et al. (2013)
demonstrate the one-way causality between inflation and
unemployment, implying that inflation affects unemploy-
ment but not the way around. The study also suggests that
the Pakistani policymakers maintain the equilibrium point
between inflation, unemployment, and interest rate to con-
trol for economic shocks. Lack of focus on one of the three
variables likely affects the economy. Still using the Pakistani
data, Zaman et al. (2011) find the long-term relationship
and one-way causality between inflation and unemploy-
ment, denoting that inflation causes unemployment but not
vice versa. The results also indicate that increasing inflation
likely increases employment opportunities that eventually
facilitates growth. The study empirically confirms the ex-
istence of the Phillips curve in Pakistan, both in the short-
term and in the long-term. Nigeria also exhibits the one-way
causality between inflation and unemployment by Sa’idu
2 G. Sasongko, A. D. Huruta. The causality between inflation
and unemployment: the Indonesian evidence
and Muhammad (2015) that indicating inflation leads to
unemployment but not the other way around. Their results
recommend the joint efforts of all policymakers to restruc-
ture the economy to manage price instability and improve
the infrastructures.
Further, Katria et al. (2011) who analyze the South Asian
Association for Regional Cooperation (SAARC) countries,
find a negative relationship between inflation and unem-
ployment. Their results indicate that the collaboration be-
tween monetary and fiscal policies manages to stabilize the
business cycle. Next, the Nigerian study by Okafor et al.
(2016) indicates that inflation negatively affects unemploy-
ment. Their results recommend that policymakers not only
rely on monetary targets but also on output targets through
the economy deepening to maintain the optimal inflation
rate and the minimal unemployment level. In a similar vein,
Cioran (2014) demonstrates that inflation negatively affects
unemployment in Romania and the European Union (EU).
The findings suggest that inflation rate is an effective instru-
ment to prevent increasing unemployment in the EU and
Romania.
Besides the negative results, other studies find the pos-
itive relationship. For example, using the Egyptian data,
Touny (2013) documents that unemployment positively
affects inflation in the long run. The results recommend
that policymakers implement their monetary policies
to overcome the inflationary pressure regardless of the
negative effects of unemployment. Further, Israel (2015)
who analyzes several developed countries such as France,
Germany, the UK, and the US, show the long-term posi-
tive relationship between inflation and unemployment.
This positive relationship is closely related to the political
intervention. The condition causes two problems, namely:
(1) monetary expansion on the income and wealth distribu-
tion leads to the increasing gap between the poor and the
rich. The increasing gap causes the labor market to be less
flexible and increases unemployment, (2) monetary expan-
sion causes less fluctuation but eventually increases unem-
ployment. Using the Uni European Countries data, Pallis
(2006) investigated the relationship between inflation and
unemployment in the 10 new European Union countries
find that in almost all countries the interaction between the
price inflation rate and the unemployment level took place
in a rather long time period, reaching in some cases the
lag of year four. In Pakistan, Ul-Haq et al. (2012) provided
further support for the existence of a long-term relationship
between unemployment and inflation. On the other hand,
the outcomes of VECM revealed a positive and significant
correlation between inflation and unemployment either in
the long term or the short term.
Other studies demonstrate the two-way causality be-
tween inflation and unemployment. For example, Arshad
(2014) shows the two-way causality between inflation rate
and unemployment in Pakistan, implying that inflation
causes unemployment, and unemployment causes infla-
tion. The data suggest that inflation rate explains the vari-
ance of unemployment better than economic growth while
unemployment contributes to the variance of inflation more
than economic growth. In Sri Lanka, Thayaparan (2014)
finds the two-way causality between inflation and unem-
ployment, implying that inflation causes unemployment
and unemployment causes inflation. The findings indicate
that both unemployment and inflation significantly affect
the Sri Lankan macroeconomic conditions. Next Bhattarai
(2016) finds bidirectional causality as well as cointegrating
relationships between unemployment and inflation among
the OECD countries. Estimates of a vector autoregression
(VAR) model on these trade-offs also support such hypoth-
esis.
Overall, these studies show varying results such as
one-way causality, two-way causality, and no causal rela-
tionship between inflation and unemployment. Further,
these studies also use different analytical models, such as
Granger Causality, Johansen Cointegration, Autoregressive
Distributive Lag, Error Correction Model, Vector Error
Correction Model, Panel Data, Vector Autoregression, and
etc. It can be concluded from the previous discussion that
there is an uncertain relationship between inflation and
unemployment of different economies in the certain period.
2. Research methods
This study uses the secondary data from the central bu-
reau of statistics and the world bank publication. More
specifically, the study relied on the time-series data from
1984 to 2017. Further Granger Causality and Vector
Autoregression used to analyze the data. Before running
the Granger Causality and Vector Autoregression model,
this study initially ran the stationary and the lag length test.
The following are the models for the stationary test and the
test statistic (Brooks 2008).
ΔYt = ϕYt – 1 + ϕt; (1)
. (2)
After running the stationary test, this study ran the lag
length test. There are various approaches to select the opti-
mal lag length, such as Likelihood Ratio, Final Prediction
Error, Akaike Information Criterion and Schwarz
Information Criterion (Rosadi 2012). This study uses the
Akaike Information Criterion (AIC). The minimum value
of the AIC suggests the optimal lag (Ivanov and Kilian
2005). After completing the lag length test, this study ran
the Granger Causality test (Rosadi 2012):
(3)
Business: Theory and Practice, 2019, 20: 1–10 3
(4)
The above equation indicates that Xt is inflation, and
Yt is unemployment, while μt and Vt are error terms that
are assumed to contain no serial correlation and m = n =
r = s. The Granger Causality test produces four possible
results as represented by the following equations:
1. If Σaj ≠ 0 and Σbj = 0, then there is a one-way
causality from inflation to unemployment.
2. If Σaj = 0 and Σbj ≠ 0, then there is a one-way
causality from unemployment to inflation.
3. If Σaj = 0 and Σbj = 0, then there is no causal re-
lationship between inflation and unemployment.
4. If Σaj ≠ 0 and Σbj ≠ 0, then there is a two-way
causality between inflation and unemployment.
Further, this study ran the Vector Autoregression
after completing the Granger Causality test. The Vector
Autoregression (VAR) is commonly used for forecast-
ing systems of interrelated time series and for analyz-
ing the dynamic impact of random disturbances on the
system of variables. The reduced form VAR approach
sidesteps the need for structural modeling by treating
every endogenous variable in the system as a function
of p-lagged values of all of the endogenous variables in
the system. The following is the equation in the Vector
Autoregression (p) with k-endogen variable yt = (y1t , y2t ,
…,ykt) (Lütkepohl 2006).
yt = A1yt–1 + … + Apyt–p + Cxt + ∈ t , (5)
where:
yt = (y1t , y2t ,…,ykt)′ is a k × 1 vector of endogenous
variables;
xt = (x1t , x2t ,…,xdt)′ is a d × 1 vector of exogenous
variables;
A1, …, Ap are k × k matrices of lag coefficients to be
estimated;
C is a d × k matrix of exogenous variable coefficients
to be estimated;
∈ t = (∈ 1t , ∈ 2t , …, ∈ kt)′ is a k × 1 white noise innova-
tion process, with E(∈ t) = 0, E(∈ t ∈ t′) = ∑∈ , and E(∈ t
∈ s′) = 0 for t ≠ s.
3. Results
Table 1 below shows the results of the stationarity test using
the Augmented Dickey-Fuller (ADF) method.
Table 1 indicates that inflation is stationary at the order
of integration of level or I(0) while the unemployment level
Table 1. Stationarity test
Variable p-value Conclusion
Inflation 0.0000* I(0)
Unemployment 0.3012 the series is not stationary
DUnemployment** 0.0000* I(1)
*indicates the rejection of the null hypothesis at 5% of
significance
level.
** DUnemployment implies that Unemployment at the first
diffe-
rence [I(1)].
Table 2. Lag length test
Lag LogL LR FPE AIC SC HQ
0 –151.4651 NA 197.5714 10.96179 11.05695 10.99088
1 –150.5083 1.708562 245.9338 11.17917 11.46464 11.26644
2 –145.1985 8.723246 225.3365 11.08561 11.56140 11.23106
3 –125.0476 30.22635* 72.08667* 9.931972* 10.59807*
10.13561*
4 –121.2335 5.176270 74.94396 9.945251 10.80167 10.20707
5 –120.3520 1.070367 97.66239 10.16800 11.21473 10.48800
*indicates the optimal lag.
is not stationary at the order of integration of level, prompt-
ing us to have the first difference technique. The order 1
or I(1) differencing shows that DUnemployment does not
contain the unit root anymore because it is now stationary.
Further, determine the optimal length of lag by using Lag
Length Test as can be seen in Table 2.
Table 2 suggests the optimal lag to indicate the depen-
dence of a variable on its lagged value and other endogenous
variables is lag 3, implying that we have to use lag 3 to inves-
tigate the causality between inflation and DUnemployment.
This decision is indicated by the Akaike Information
Criterion (AIC) value of 9.931972 that is smaller than the
AIC values at the other lags. After ran the lag length test, this
study ran the Granger Causality test using lag 3. The results
of Granger Causality test can be seen in Table 3.
Table 3 reveals that the null hypothesis proposing
that DUnemployment does not Granger Cause infla-
tion is rejected, implying that DUnemployment exhibits
the Granger Cause on inflation. The results suggest that
DUnemployment granger cause inflation, but not vice
4 G. Sasongko, A. D. Huruta. The causality between inflation
and unemployment: the Indonesian evidence
versa. The decision of rejecting the null hypothesis is based
on the probability value of 2.E-08 that is lower than α = 5%.
After ran the Granger Causality, this study ran the Vector
Autoregression. Variables in a Vector Autoregression
model are determined simultaneously and rely more on
historic patterns of data to establish relations between
unemployment and inflation than economic theories
(Bhattarai 2016). The results of Vector Autoregression
can be seen in Table 4.
Table 4 indicates that a simple Vector Autoregression
model with three lags on inflation and DUnemployment
shows that Inflation is significantly influenced by DUnem-
ployment(–2), DUnemployment(–3) and inflation(–1). It
implies that the influence of DUnemploy ment(–2), DUnem-
ployment(–3) and inflation(–1) have a large contribution to
the movement of inflation in Indonesia. Estimates of Vector
Autoregression also support by the Impulse Response
Functions (IRFs). The results of the Impulse Response
Functions (IRFs) can be seen in Figure 1.
Impulse Response Functions (IRFs) was calculated for
DUnemployment and inflation to address the reaction of
the economy to external changes (shocks). The results of
the IRFs analysis show that there is a trade-off between
inflation and DUnemployment as shown by the IRFs of
DUnemployment to inflation. Overall, estimate results of
Granger Causality, Vector Autoregression, and Impulse
Response Functions (IRFs) prove that the DUnemployment
is more instrumental to explain inflation in Indonesia.
Further, this result is supported by Touny (2013) who
finds the positive effect of unemployment on inflation. The
normalized cointegration equation reveals that unemploy-
ment gap has a long-run positive effect on the changes in
the inflation rate, which is consistent with “Lucas Critique”
where a policy of inflation would fail to reduce the unem-
ployment rate in the long run, because workers would
eventually adjust their expectations of inflation. Further,
the more rapid the reduction in the unemployment rate,
the less disinflation is achieved at each unemployment rate
level. Even at the cases where the unemployment rate is very
high, the inflation rate falls little and thus the economy is
moving too rapidly out of the recession (Pallis 2006). Other
findings by Ul-Haq et al. (2012) also suggest that policy
makers should pay special attention to this relationship
between inflation and unemployment when they are going
to design macroeconomic policies.
Thus, when inflation does not support DUnemployment,
it is necessary to analyze factors that affect DUnemployment.
Table 5 below presents the information on the number of
Table 3. Granger causality test
Pairwise Granger Causality Tests
Sample: 1984 2017
Lags: 3
Null Hypothesis: Obs F-Statistic Prob.
Inflation does not Granger Cause DUnemployment 30 0.72869
0.5454
Dunemployment does not Granger Cause Inflation 33.0657 2.E-
08
Table 4. VAR Model of inflation and DUnemployment for
Indonesia (1984–2017)
DUnemployment Inflation
Coefficients t-prob Coefficients t-prob
DUnemployment(–1) –0.135523 0.20747 0.709939 1.30180
DUnemployment(–2) –0.181229 0.20753 –6.937364 1.30223
DUnemployment(–3) 0.217161 0.24175 11.60203 1.51692
Inflation(–1) 0.024945 0.01742 0.421936 0.10934
Inflation(–2) 0.003714 0.01524 0.042180 0.09564
Inflation(–3) –0.006079 0.01513 0.021545 0.09495
Constant –0.186910 0.34132 4.400302 2.14168
R2 0.124570 0.813392
F-statistic 0.545466 16.70883
Log-likehood –39.33832 –94.43436
AIC 3.089221 6.762290
Swarz SC 3.416167 7.089236
Business: Theory and Practice, 2019, 20: 1–10 5
Figure 1. Impulse responses to DUnemployment and inflation
shocks
Table 5. The Population 15 Years of age or over by the main
employment status (2001–2017) (source: Badan Pusat Statistik
(2017a), processed))
Number Main Employment Status
2001 2017
Amount % Amount %
1 Self-employed 17,451,704 19.22 21,849,573 17.54
2 Employer Assisted by Temporary/ Unpaid Worker 20,329,073
22.39 21,275,899 17.08
3 Employer Assisted by Permanent/ Paid Worker 2,788,878 3.07
4,446,024 3.57
4 Employee 26,579,000 29.27 47,420,633 38.08
5 Casual Agricultural Worker 3,633,126 4.00 5,360,306 4.30
6 Casual Non-Agricultural Worker 2,439,035 2.69 6,021,760
4.84
7 Family/ Unpaid Worker 17,586,601 19.37 18,164,654 14.59
8 No Answer – – – –
Total 90,807,417 100.00 124,538,849 100.00
the population 15 years of age or over who worked by the
main employment status.
Table 5 indicates the sharp increase in the number of
the working-age population with the employee status, both
in absolute and relative terms. The number of employees
in 2001 was 26,579,000 or 29.7% of the total working age
population. The number increased to 47,420,633 or 38.08%
of the total working age population in 2017. Increased in-
vestment mainly drives the increasing number of employ-
ees. Djambaska and Lozanoska (2015), Yelwa et al. (2015),
Touny (2013), Israel (2015), Ul-Haq et al. (2012), Bhattarai
(2016), and Pallis (2006) support the results by arguing that
6 G. Sasongko, A. D. Huruta. The causality between inflation
and unemployment: the Indonesian evidence
investment is a determining factor in reducing unemploy-
ment.
Further, another factor that affects the number of un-
employment is the industry in which the population work.
Table 6 below shows the data on the population 15 years of
age or over who worked by industry.
The proportion of the population above 15 years who
worked at the primary sectors (agriculture, plantation,
forestry, hunting, and fishery) declined sharply. In 1991,
53.29% of the working population worked in the primary
sectors, and proportion declined to 31.74% in 2016. The
agricultural sector dominates the primary sectors because
of most population work in this sector (Thayaparan 2014,
Yelwa et al. 2015, Kebschull 1987, Israel 2015). Edelman
(2013) confirms the findings by suggesting that farmers
in Latin America and Indonesia live in communities with
exclusive land rights and most of them use the lands for
agricultural activities. The agricultural works in Indonesia
are heavily affected by the season factor, especially before
2005 because of the less developed irrigation system. More
specifically, the agricultural sector greatly depends on the
sufficient availability of rainfall. Farmers begin to culti-
vate their soils after rain falls. Rain usually starts to fall in
October and the dry season starts in April. The following
Table 6 displays the open unemployment level based on
the February and August surveys. February is in the rainy
season while August is in the dry season. The open unem-
ployment rate was higher in August, a month in the dry
season than in February, a rainy month. The average August
unemployment rate was 8,599,944 while in February the
average unemployment level was 8,599,676. The propor-
tion of the population working in the agricultural sector
was so high that the season factor significantly affected the
unemployment rate. However, the annual difference of the
unemployment level between these two months tended to
decline. There was even no difference of the open unemploy-
ment level between February and August in 2017 (Badan
Pusat Statistik 2017d). Further estimates of an Independent
Sample T Test also support the data. Estimate results can
be seen in Table 7.
The significance value (2 tailed) of 1.000 is bigger than
the tolerance value of 5% (0.05) implies that there is no
difference between February and August unemployment
rate. The more developed irrigation system reduce the farm-
ers’ dependence on rainfall and eventually on the season.
Next, the Indonesian working-age population who attended
Table 6. Population 15 years of age or over who worked by
main industry (1991–2016) (source: Badan Pusat Statistik
(2017b),
processed))
Number Main Industry
1991 2016
Amount % Amount %
1 Agriculture, Plantation, Forestry, Hunting, and Fisheries
39,385,946 53.29 38,291,111 31.74
2 Mining and Quarrying 551,581 0.75 1,311,834 1.09
3 Manufacturing Industry 7,712,468 1.43 15,975,086 1.24
4 Electricity, Gas, and Water 148,480 0.20 403,824 0.33
5 Construction 2,415,002 3.27 7,707,297 6.39
6 Trade, Restaurants, and Accomodation Services 11,190,391
1.14 28,495,436 23.62
7 Transportation, Warehousing, and Communication 2,475,803
3.35 5,192,491 4.30
8 Financial, Real Estate, and Business Services 515,401 0.70
3,481,598 2.89
9 Community, Social, and Personal Services 9,377,036 12.69
19,789,020 1.40
10 Undefined 139,516 0.19 – –
Total 73,911,624 100.00 120,647,697 100.00
Table 7. Independent Sample T Test for Unemployment on
February and August (1986–2017)
Levene’s Test
for Equality of
Variances
t-test for Equality of Means
F Sig. t Df
Sig.
(2-tailed)
Mean
Difference
Std. Error
Difference
95% Confidence Interval of
the Difference
Lower Upper
Unmpl
Equal variances
assumed
.002 .967 .000 24 1.000 –268.00000 6.06551E5 –1.25213E6
1.25159E6
Equal variances
not assumed
.000 23.945 1.000 –268.00000 6.06551E5 –1.25228E6
1.25174E6
Business: Theory and Practice, 2019, 20: 1–10 7
school or performed the housekeeping increased. The num-
ber of economically inactive women due to housekeeping
increased both in absolute and relative terms (Ehrenberg
and Smith 2012). In 2005, the number of the working age
population who performed the housekeeping (mostly wom-
en) was 17,275,478 or 17.08% of the total labor force. The
number increased to 36,078,772 or 18.78% of the labor force
in 2017 (Badan Pusat Statistik 2017c). The estimates of an
Independent Sample T Test also support the data. Estimate
results can be seen in Table 8.
The significance value (2 tailed) of 0.000 is lower than the
tolerance value of 5% (0.05) implies that there is a difference
between the Indonesian working-age population who at-
tended school and performed the housekeeping. Ehrenberg
and Smith (2012) confirm the data by arguing that women
spend a significant portion of their time to housekeeping
such as cooking or taking care of their children. Women
prefer housekeeping to enter the labor market because
housekeeping is also a productive activity.
Further, the number of the population 15 years of age
or over who attended school increased from 9,147,830 in
2005 to 15,244,852 in 2017. However, the proportion of
the working-age population who attended school decreased
from 9.04% in 2005 to 7.94% in 2017. Higher school atten-
dance decreases the number of unemployment. Hubacek
et al. (2007) support the findings by demonstrating that
the economic success of the developing Asian countries
enhances the quality of life of their population. Most Asian
population experience the transition from poverty to suf-
ficient fulfillment of food and clothes. Further, they aspire
to not only meet their basic needs of food and clothes, but
also to enjoy a higher quality of life from highly nutritious
food, life comfort, medical treatments, and other highly
qualified services.
Conclusions
This study suggests the one-way relationship between inf-
lation and DUnemployment. More specifically, the Granger
Causality, Vector Autoregression, and Impulse Response
Functions (IRFs) model show that from 1984 to 2017,
DUnemployment causes inflation, but not vice versa. The
results imply that the Phillips model (Phllips 1958) that
proposes the reciprocal relationship between inflation and
unemployment is not empirically supported in Indonesia.
These findings also different with the most recently by
Blanchard (2016) who find that The US Phillips curve is
alive and well (or at least as well as it has been in the past).
Various factors affect the Indonesian unemployment
rate, such as: (1) The season factor significantly affects un-
employment, albeit with the declining magnitude, because
the agricultural sector still absorbs a significant portion of
the Indonesian labor force; (2) Increased income encour-
ages young labor force (15–19 years) to delay entering the
labor market but to continue their studies; and (3) Better
economic condition also increases the number of non-labor
force. More specifically, women prefer becoming house-
wives (caring for their households) in entering the labor
market because caring for households is also a productive
activity (Ehrenberg and Smith 2012).
Inflation is a less effective policy instrument to over-
come the unemployment problem in Indonesia. This ar-
gument implies that increasing the inflation rate is inef-
fective to reduce the unemployment rate. Numerous facts
indicate that other variables affect the Indonesian unem-
ployment rate. However, it is viable to increase the unem-
ployment rate to control inflation, although this policy
has to be implemented carefully. Further, the Indonesian
geographical condition that consists of thousands of is-
lands likely causes the implementation of macro policies
to take a longer time because of the greater needs to adjust
for the inter-region differences. Thus, the use of the panel
data model likely accounts for the possible inter-region
variances better.
References
Al-zeaud H (2014) The trade-off between unemployment and
inflation evidence from causality test for Jordan. International
Journal of Humanities and Social Science 4 (4): 103-111.
Table 8. Independent Sample T Test for Working Age Between
Attend School and Housekeeping (1986–2017)
Levene’s Test
for Equality of
Variances
t-test for Equality of Means
F Sig. T df
Sig.
(2-tailed)
Mean
Difference
Std. Error
Difference
95% Confidence Interval of
the Difference
Lower Upper
WorkAge
Equal varian-
ces assumed
4.160 .046 –48.096 60 .000 –9.88226 .20547 –10.29326 –
9.47126
Equal va-
riances not
assumed
–48.096 51.170 .000 –9.88226 .20547 –10.29472 –9.46980
8 G. Sasongko, A. D. Huruta. The causality between inflation
and unemployment: the Indonesian evidence
Arshad I (2014) Examining relationship between
macroeconomic
variables using Var Approach. In: Proceedings of the 2014
International Conference on Industrial Engineering and
Operations Management. Bali, 2393-2401 http://ieomsociety.
org/ieom2014/pdfs/510.pdf
Badan Pusat Statistik (2017a) Penduduk 15 Tahun Ke Atas
Menurut Status Pekerjaan Utama 1986–2017 https://www.
bps.go.id/statictable/2009/04/16/971/penduduk-15-tahun-ke-
atasmenurut-%0Astatus-pekerjaan-utama-1986---2017.html
Badan Pusat Statistik (2017b) Penduduk 15 Tahun Ke Atas yang
Bekerja menurut Lapangan Pekerjaan Utama 1986–2017
https://www.bps.go.id/statictable/2009/04/16/970/penduduk-
15-tahun-ke-atas-yang-bekerja-menurut-lapangan-pekerjaan-
utama-1986---2017.html
Badan Pusat Statistik (2017c) Penduduk Berumur 15 tahun ke
atas
menurut jenis kegiatan tahun 1986–2017 https://www.bps.
go.id/statictable/2009/04/16/969/penduduk-berumur-15-ta-
hun-ke-atas-menurut-jenis-kegiatan-tahun-1986---2017.html
Badan Pusat Statistik (2017d) Tingkat Pengangguran Terbuka
(TPT) Menurut Provinsi, 1986–2017 https://www.bps.go.id/
statictable/2014/09/15/981/tingkat-pengangguran-terbuka-
tpt-menurut-provinsi-1986---2017.html
Bank Indonesia (2004) Laporan Perekonomian Indonesia Tahun
1998/1999. Jakarta. https://www.bi.go.id/id/publikasi/laporan-
tahunan/perekonomian/Pages/LapTah 1998 1999.aspx
Bank Indonesia (2017) Tujuan Kebijakan Moneter Bank In-
donesia http://www.bi.go.id/id/moneter/tujuan-kebijakan/
Contents/Default.aspx
Benati L (2015) The long-run Phillips curve: A structural VAR
investigation. Journal of Monetary Economics 76: 15-28.
https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jmoneco.2015.06.007
Bhattarai K (2016) Unemployment-inflation trade-offs in OECD
countries. Economic modelling 58 (2016): 93-103. https://doi.
org/10.1016/j.econmod.2016.05.007
Blanchard O (2016) The Phillips curve: Back to the ’60s?
Ameri-
can Economic Review 106 (5): 31-34. https://doi.org/10.1257/
aer.p20161003
Brooks C (2008) Introductory econometrics for finance (2nd
ed) Cambridge University Press. https://doi.org/10.1017/
CBO9780511841644
Caporale GM, Škare M (2011) Short- and long-run linkages
between employment growth, inflation and output growth :
evidence from a large panel. Economic and Finance Wor-
king Paper. London https://www.brunel.ac.uk/__data/assets/
pdf_file/0011/127487/1117.pdf
Cioran Z (2014) Monetary policy, inflation and the causal
relation
between the inflation rate and some of the macroeconomic
variables. Procedia Economics and Finance 16 (May): 391-
401. https://doi.org/10.1016/S2212-5671(14)00818-1
Djambaska E, Lozanoska A (2015) Foreign direct investment
and
unemployment evidence from the republic of Macedonia.
International Journal of Economics, Commerce and Mana-
gement United Kingdom, III(12): 73-85.
Edelman M (2013) What is a peasant? What are peasantries? A
Briefing paper on issues of definition. Intergovernmental Wor-
king Group on a United Nations Declaration on the Rights of
Peasants and Other People Working in Rural Areas, Geneva,
15-19 July 2013. Geneva http://www.ohchr.org/Documents/
HRBodies/HRCouncil/WGPleasants/MarcEdelman.pdf
Ehrenberg RG, Smith RS (2012) Modern Labor Economics:
Theory and Public Policy (Donna Battista, Ed) (11th ed)
Boston: Pearson Education, Inc. http://fac.ksu.edu.sa/sites/
default/files/Modern_labor_economics__theory_and_pub-
lic_policy_0.pdf
Furuoka F (2007) Does the “Phillips curve” really exist? New
empirical evidence from Malaysia. Economics Bulletin 5 (16):
1-14. http://economicsbulletin.vanderbilt.edu/2007/volume5/
EB-07E20006A.pdf
Furuoka F (2008) Unemployment and Inflation in the
Philippines:
new evidence from Vector Error Correction Model. Philippo-
ne Journal of Development XXXV (1): 93-106. https://dirp4.
pids.gov.ph/ris/pjd/pidspjd08-1unemployment.pdf
Hubacek K, Guan D, Barua A (2007) Changing lifestyles and
consumption patterns in developing countries: A scenario
analysis for China and India. Futures 39 (9): 1084-1096.
https://core.ac.uk/download/pdf/51098.pdf
Israel K (2015) Reconsidering the long-run relationship between
inflation and unemployment http://www2.gcc.edu/dept/econ/
assc/Papers 2015/ASSC 2015 - Israel, Karl-Friedrich.pdf
Ivanov V, Kilian L (2005) A practitioner’s guide to lag order
selection for VAR impulse response analysis. Studies in Non-
linear Dynamics & Econometrics 9 (1): 1-36.
Katria S, Bhutto NA, Butt F, Domki AA, Khawaja HA, Khalid J
(2011) Tradeoff between inflation and unemployment. In:
Proceedings of 2nd International Conference on Business
Management, 1-18 https://www.umt.edu.pk/icobm2012/
pdf/2C-90P.pdf
Kebschull D (1987) The role of the agricultural sector in the
South by. Intereconomics, 125-126. https://doi.org/10.1007/
BF02932233
Keynes JM (1936) The general theory of employment, interest,
and money. MacMillan and Cambridge University Press.
Kogid M, Asid R, Mulok D, Lily J, Loganathan N (2011) Inf-
lation-unemployment trade-off relationship in Malaysia.
Asian Journal of Business and Management Sciences 1 (1):
100-108 http://medcontent.metapress.com/index/A65RM-
03P4874243N.pdf%5Cnhttp://www.ajbms.org/articlepdf/
ajbms_2011_1124.pdf
Lütkepohl H (2006) New introduction to multiple time series
analysis. New York: Springer-Verlag.
Mahmood Y, Bokhari R, Aslam M (2013) Trade-off between
Inflation, Interest and unemployment rate of Pakistan: A coin-
tegration analysis. Pakistan Journal of Commerce and Social
Sciences 7 (3): 482-492
http://www.jespk.net/publications/140.pdf
Mankiw NG, Euston Q, Wilson P (2013) Principles of
economics:
an Asian edition (2nd ed) Singapore: Cengage Learning Asia.
Okafor IG, Chijindu EH, Ugochukwu US (2016) Responsiveness
of unemployment to inflation: empirical evidence from Ni-
geria. International Journal of Scientific Research in Science
and Technology 2 (4): 173-179 https://www.researchgate.
net/publication/311349523_Responsiveness_of_Unemploy-
ment_to_Inflation_Empirical_Evidence_from_Nigeria
Pallis D (2006) The trade-off between inflation and unemploy-
ment in the New European Union Member-States. Interna-
tional Research Journal of Finance and Economics (1): 80-88.
Phllips AW (1958) The relation between unemployment and the
rate of change of money wage rates in the United Kingdom.
Economica 25 (100): 283-299.
Business: Theory and Practice, 2019, 20: 1–10 9
Rosadi D (2012) Ekonometrika dan Analisis Runtun Waktu
Terapan Dengan Eviews. Yogyakarta: ANDI.
Sa’idu BM, Muhammad AA (2015) Do Unemployment and
inflation substantially affect economic growth? Journal of
Economics and Development Studies 3 (2): 132-139 https://
doi.org/10.15640/jeds.v3n2a13
Sasongko G, Huruta AD (2018) Monetary policy and the
causality
between inflation and money supply in Indonesia. Business:
Theory and Practice 19: 80-87. https://doi.org/10.3846/
btp.2018.09
Ştefan C, Bratu A (2016) The inflation-unemployment tradeoff
in a macroeconometric model. British Journal of Economics,
Finance and Management Sciences 12 (1): 22-31 http://www.
ajournal.co.uk/EFpdfs/EFvolume12(1)/EFVol.12 (1) Article
3.pdf
Thayaparan A (2014) Impact of inflation on economic growth
in Sri Lanka: a study of time series analysis. Global Jour-
nal of Management and Business Research: B Economics
and Commerce 13 (5): 45-54. https://doi.org/10.11648/j.
jwer.20160501.11
Touny MA (2013) Investigate the long-run trade-off betwe-
en inflation and unemployment in Egypt. International
Journal of Economics and Finance 5 (7): 115-125. https://
doi.org/10.5539/ijef.v5n7p115
Ul-Haq I, Khan S, Khan A, Ahmed E (2012) Phillips curve or
locus critique: time series evidence from Pakistan. Journal of
Economics and Behavioral Studies 4 (4): 190-193 https://www.
researchgate.net/publication/301551781_Revisiting_the_Phil-
lips_Curve_and_the_Lucas_Critique
Umaru A, Zubairu AA (2012) An empirical analysis of the re-
lationship between unemployment and inflation in Nigeria
from 1977–2009. Economics and Finance Review 1 (12):
42-61. https://doi.org/10.1111/1467-8268.00061
Yelwa M, David OOK, Omoniyi AE (2015) Analysis of the re-
lationship between inflation, unemployment and economic
growth in Nigeria: 1987–2012. Applied Economics and
Finance 2 (3): 102-109. https://doi.org/10.11114/aef.v2i3.943
Zaman K, Khan MM, Ahmad M, Ikram W (2011) Inflation,
unemployment and the NAIRU in Pakistan (1975–2009).
International Journal of Economics and Finance 3 (1): 245-
254. https://doi.org/10.1016/S2212-5671(12)00015-9
10 G. Sasongko, A. D. Huruta. The causality between inflation
and unemployment: the Indonesian evidence
Rethinking The Current Inflation Target Range In South Afric.docx

More Related Content

Similar to Rethinking The Current Inflation Target Range In South Afric.docx

Finding Optimal Proportion of Budgetary Sources to Fund Government Expenditure
Finding Optimal Proportion of Budgetary Sources to Fund Government ExpenditureFinding Optimal Proportion of Budgetary Sources to Fund Government Expenditure
Finding Optimal Proportion of Budgetary Sources to Fund Government ExpenditureIRJET Journal
 
Inflation Rate, Foreign Direct Investment, Interest Rate, and Economic Growth...
Inflation Rate, Foreign Direct Investment, Interest Rate, and Economic Growth...Inflation Rate, Foreign Direct Investment, Interest Rate, and Economic Growth...
Inflation Rate, Foreign Direct Investment, Interest Rate, and Economic Growth...ijtsrd
 
Analysis of the relationship between fiscal deficits and external sector perf...
Analysis of the relationship between fiscal deficits and external sector perf...Analysis of the relationship between fiscal deficits and external sector perf...
Analysis of the relationship between fiscal deficits and external sector perf...Alexander Decker
 
Dynamic Impact of Money Supply on Inflation: Evidence from ECOWAS Member States
Dynamic Impact of Money Supply on Inflation: Evidence from ECOWAS Member StatesDynamic Impact of Money Supply on Inflation: Evidence from ECOWAS Member States
Dynamic Impact of Money Supply on Inflation: Evidence from ECOWAS Member Statesiosrjce
 
An Analysis of the Relationship between Fiscal Deficits and Selected Macroeco...
An Analysis of the Relationship between Fiscal Deficits and Selected Macroeco...An Analysis of the Relationship between Fiscal Deficits and Selected Macroeco...
An Analysis of the Relationship between Fiscal Deficits and Selected Macroeco...IOSR Journals
 
C431017
C431017C431017
C431017aijbm
 
Effect of Government Policies on Price Stability in Nigeria
Effect of Government Policies on Price Stability in NigeriaEffect of Government Policies on Price Stability in Nigeria
Effect of Government Policies on Price Stability in Nigeriaijtsrd
 
ANALYZING AND MEASURING THE CAUSAL RELATIONSHIP BETWEEN INFLATION AND UNEMPLO...
ANALYZING AND MEASURING THE CAUSAL RELATIONSHIP BETWEEN INFLATION AND UNEMPLO...ANALYZING AND MEASURING THE CAUSAL RELATIONSHIP BETWEEN INFLATION AND UNEMPLO...
ANALYZING AND MEASURING THE CAUSAL RELATIONSHIP BETWEEN INFLATION AND UNEMPLO...indexPub
 
Dynamics of monetary policy and output nexus in nigeria
Dynamics of monetary policy and output nexus in nigeriaDynamics of monetary policy and output nexus in nigeria
Dynamics of monetary policy and output nexus in nigeriaAlexander Decker
 
Budget Deficit and Economic Growth in Liberia: An Empirical Investigation
Budget Deficit and Economic Growth in Liberia: An Empirical InvestigationBudget Deficit and Economic Growth in Liberia: An Empirical Investigation
Budget Deficit and Economic Growth in Liberia: An Empirical InvestigationAJHSSR Journal
 
Does government spending spur economic growth evidence from nigeria
Does government spending spur economic growth  evidence from nigeriaDoes government spending spur economic growth  evidence from nigeria
Does government spending spur economic growth evidence from nigeriaAlexander Decker
 
The nexus between budget deficit and inflation in the nigerian
The nexus between budget deficit and inflation in the nigerianThe nexus between budget deficit and inflation in the nigerian
The nexus between budget deficit and inflation in the nigerianAlexander Decker
 
B321024
B321024B321024
B321024aijbm
 
30 ranjan kumar mohanty fiscal deficit economic growth nexus in india a coint...
30 ranjan kumar mohanty fiscal deficit economic growth nexus in india a coint...30 ranjan kumar mohanty fiscal deficit economic growth nexus in india a coint...
30 ranjan kumar mohanty fiscal deficit economic growth nexus in india a coint...Gamidi Saikiran
 
Monetary Policy Shocks and Agricultural Output Growth in Nigeria
Monetary Policy Shocks and Agricultural Output Growth in NigeriaMonetary Policy Shocks and Agricultural Output Growth in Nigeria
Monetary Policy Shocks and Agricultural Output Growth in Nigeriaiosrjce
 

Similar to Rethinking The Current Inflation Target Range In South Afric.docx (20)

Finding Optimal Proportion of Budgetary Sources to Fund Government Expenditure
Finding Optimal Proportion of Budgetary Sources to Fund Government ExpenditureFinding Optimal Proportion of Budgetary Sources to Fund Government Expenditure
Finding Optimal Proportion of Budgetary Sources to Fund Government Expenditure
 
Inflation Rate, Foreign Direct Investment, Interest Rate, and Economic Growth...
Inflation Rate, Foreign Direct Investment, Interest Rate, and Economic Growth...Inflation Rate, Foreign Direct Investment, Interest Rate, and Economic Growth...
Inflation Rate, Foreign Direct Investment, Interest Rate, and Economic Growth...
 
Analysis of the relationship between fiscal deficits and external sector perf...
Analysis of the relationship between fiscal deficits and external sector perf...Analysis of the relationship between fiscal deficits and external sector perf...
Analysis of the relationship between fiscal deficits and external sector perf...
 
Dynamic Impact of Money Supply on Inflation: Evidence from ECOWAS Member States
Dynamic Impact of Money Supply on Inflation: Evidence from ECOWAS Member StatesDynamic Impact of Money Supply on Inflation: Evidence from ECOWAS Member States
Dynamic Impact of Money Supply on Inflation: Evidence from ECOWAS Member States
 
An Analysis of the Relationship between Fiscal Deficits and Selected Macroeco...
An Analysis of the Relationship between Fiscal Deficits and Selected Macroeco...An Analysis of the Relationship between Fiscal Deficits and Selected Macroeco...
An Analysis of the Relationship between Fiscal Deficits and Selected Macroeco...
 
C431017
C431017C431017
C431017
 
Interest Rate and Growth Nexus in Nigeria: The ARDL – Bound Test Approach
Interest Rate and Growth Nexus in Nigeria: The ARDL – Bound Test ApproachInterest Rate and Growth Nexus in Nigeria: The ARDL – Bound Test Approach
Interest Rate and Growth Nexus in Nigeria: The ARDL – Bound Test Approach
 
The Determinants of Inflation in West Africa
The Determinants of Inflation in West AfricaThe Determinants of Inflation in West Africa
The Determinants of Inflation in West Africa
 
Effect of Government Policies on Price Stability in Nigeria
Effect of Government Policies on Price Stability in NigeriaEffect of Government Policies on Price Stability in Nigeria
Effect of Government Policies on Price Stability in Nigeria
 
ANALYZING AND MEASURING THE CAUSAL RELATIONSHIP BETWEEN INFLATION AND UNEMPLO...
ANALYZING AND MEASURING THE CAUSAL RELATIONSHIP BETWEEN INFLATION AND UNEMPLO...ANALYZING AND MEASURING THE CAUSAL RELATIONSHIP BETWEEN INFLATION AND UNEMPLO...
ANALYZING AND MEASURING THE CAUSAL RELATIONSHIP BETWEEN INFLATION AND UNEMPLO...
 
Dynamics of monetary policy and output nexus in nigeria
Dynamics of monetary policy and output nexus in nigeriaDynamics of monetary policy and output nexus in nigeria
Dynamics of monetary policy and output nexus in nigeria
 
Bank Development and Human Development in WAEMU Countries: Evidence from Pan...
 Bank Development and Human Development in WAEMU Countries: Evidence from Pan... Bank Development and Human Development in WAEMU Countries: Evidence from Pan...
Bank Development and Human Development in WAEMU Countries: Evidence from Pan...
 
Budget Deficit and Economic Growth in Liberia: An Empirical Investigation
Budget Deficit and Economic Growth in Liberia: An Empirical InvestigationBudget Deficit and Economic Growth in Liberia: An Empirical Investigation
Budget Deficit and Economic Growth in Liberia: An Empirical Investigation
 
Does government spending spur economic growth evidence from nigeria
Does government spending spur economic growth  evidence from nigeriaDoes government spending spur economic growth  evidence from nigeria
Does government spending spur economic growth evidence from nigeria
 
The nexus between budget deficit and inflation in the nigerian
The nexus between budget deficit and inflation in the nigerianThe nexus between budget deficit and inflation in the nigerian
The nexus between budget deficit and inflation in the nigerian
 
Impact of Monetary Policy on Capital Inflows in Nigeria
Impact of Monetary Policy on Capital Inflows in NigeriaImpact of Monetary Policy on Capital Inflows in Nigeria
Impact of Monetary Policy on Capital Inflows in Nigeria
 
B321024
B321024B321024
B321024
 
Inflation
InflationInflation
Inflation
 
30 ranjan kumar mohanty fiscal deficit economic growth nexus in india a coint...
30 ranjan kumar mohanty fiscal deficit economic growth nexus in india a coint...30 ranjan kumar mohanty fiscal deficit economic growth nexus in india a coint...
30 ranjan kumar mohanty fiscal deficit economic growth nexus in india a coint...
 
Monetary Policy Shocks and Agricultural Output Growth in Nigeria
Monetary Policy Shocks and Agricultural Output Growth in NigeriaMonetary Policy Shocks and Agricultural Output Growth in Nigeria
Monetary Policy Shocks and Agricultural Output Growth in Nigeria
 

More from audeleypearl

Mr. Bush, a 45-year-old middle school teacher arrives at the emergen.docx
Mr. Bush, a 45-year-old middle school teacher arrives at the emergen.docxMr. Bush, a 45-year-old middle school teacher arrives at the emergen.docx
Mr. Bush, a 45-year-old middle school teacher arrives at the emergen.docxaudeleypearl
 
Movie Project Presentation Movie TroyInclude Architecture i.docx
Movie Project Presentation Movie TroyInclude Architecture i.docxMovie Project Presentation Movie TroyInclude Architecture i.docx
Movie Project Presentation Movie TroyInclude Architecture i.docxaudeleypearl
 
Motivation and Retention Discuss the specific strategies you pl.docx
Motivation and Retention Discuss the specific strategies you pl.docxMotivation and Retention Discuss the specific strategies you pl.docx
Motivation and Retention Discuss the specific strategies you pl.docxaudeleypearl
 
Mother of the Year In recognition of superlative paren.docx
Mother of the Year         In recognition of superlative paren.docxMother of the Year         In recognition of superlative paren.docx
Mother of the Year In recognition of superlative paren.docxaudeleypearl
 
Mrs. G, a 55 year old Hispanic female, presents to the office for he.docx
Mrs. G, a 55 year old Hispanic female, presents to the office for he.docxMrs. G, a 55 year old Hispanic female, presents to the office for he.docx
Mrs. G, a 55 year old Hispanic female, presents to the office for he.docxaudeleypearl
 
Mr. Rivera is a 72-year-old patient with end stage COPD who is in th.docx
Mr. Rivera is a 72-year-old patient with end stage COPD who is in th.docxMr. Rivera is a 72-year-old patient with end stage COPD who is in th.docx
Mr. Rivera is a 72-year-old patient with end stage COPD who is in th.docxaudeleypearl
 
Mr. B, a 40-year-old avid long-distance runner previously in goo.docx
Mr. B, a 40-year-old avid long-distance runner previously in goo.docxMr. B, a 40-year-old avid long-distance runner previously in goo.docx
Mr. B, a 40-year-old avid long-distance runner previously in goo.docxaudeleypearl
 
Moving members of the organization through the change process ca.docx
Moving members of the organization through the change process ca.docxMoving members of the organization through the change process ca.docx
Moving members of the organization through the change process ca.docxaudeleypearl
 
Mr. Friend is acrime analystwith the SantaCruz, Califo.docx
Mr. Friend is acrime analystwith the SantaCruz, Califo.docxMr. Friend is acrime analystwith the SantaCruz, Califo.docx
Mr. Friend is acrime analystwith the SantaCruz, Califo.docxaudeleypearl
 
Mr. E is a pleasant, 70-year-old, black, maleSource Self, rel.docx
Mr. E is a pleasant, 70-year-old, black, maleSource Self, rel.docxMr. E is a pleasant, 70-year-old, black, maleSource Self, rel.docx
Mr. E is a pleasant, 70-year-old, black, maleSource Self, rel.docxaudeleypearl
 
Motor Milestones occur in a predictable developmental progression in.docx
Motor Milestones occur in a predictable developmental progression in.docxMotor Milestones occur in a predictable developmental progression in.docx
Motor Milestones occur in a predictable developmental progression in.docxaudeleypearl
 
Most women experience their closest friendships with those of th.docx
Most women experience their closest friendships with those of th.docxMost women experience their closest friendships with those of th.docx
Most women experience their closest friendships with those of th.docxaudeleypearl
 
Most patients with mental health disorders are not aggressive. Howev.docx
Most patients with mental health disorders are not aggressive. Howev.docxMost patients with mental health disorders are not aggressive. Howev.docx
Most patients with mental health disorders are not aggressive. Howev.docxaudeleypearl
 
Most of our class readings and discussions to date have dealt wi.docx
Most of our class readings and discussions to date have dealt wi.docxMost of our class readings and discussions to date have dealt wi.docx
Most of our class readings and discussions to date have dealt wi.docxaudeleypearl
 
Most people agree we live in stressful times. Does stress and re.docx
Most people agree we live in stressful times. Does stress and re.docxMost people agree we live in stressful times. Does stress and re.docx
Most people agree we live in stressful times. Does stress and re.docxaudeleypearl
 
Most of the ethical prescriptions of normative moral philosophy .docx
Most of the ethical prescriptions of normative moral philosophy .docxMost of the ethical prescriptions of normative moral philosophy .docx
Most of the ethical prescriptions of normative moral philosophy .docxaudeleypearl
 
Most healthcare organizations in the country are implementing qualit.docx
Most healthcare organizations in the country are implementing qualit.docxMost healthcare organizations in the country are implementing qualit.docx
Most healthcare organizations in the country are implementing qualit.docxaudeleypearl
 
More work is necessary on how to efficiently model uncertainty in ML.docx
More work is necessary on how to efficiently model uncertainty in ML.docxMore work is necessary on how to efficiently model uncertainty in ML.docx
More work is necessary on how to efficiently model uncertainty in ML.docxaudeleypearl
 
Mortgage-Backed Securities and the Financial CrisisKelly Finn.docx
Mortgage-Backed Securities and the Financial CrisisKelly Finn.docxMortgage-Backed Securities and the Financial CrisisKelly Finn.docx
Mortgage-Backed Securities and the Financial CrisisKelly Finn.docxaudeleypearl
 
Moral Development  Lawrence Kohlberg developed six stages to mora.docx
Moral Development  Lawrence Kohlberg developed six stages to mora.docxMoral Development  Lawrence Kohlberg developed six stages to mora.docx
Moral Development  Lawrence Kohlberg developed six stages to mora.docxaudeleypearl
 

More from audeleypearl (20)

Mr. Bush, a 45-year-old middle school teacher arrives at the emergen.docx
Mr. Bush, a 45-year-old middle school teacher arrives at the emergen.docxMr. Bush, a 45-year-old middle school teacher arrives at the emergen.docx
Mr. Bush, a 45-year-old middle school teacher arrives at the emergen.docx
 
Movie Project Presentation Movie TroyInclude Architecture i.docx
Movie Project Presentation Movie TroyInclude Architecture i.docxMovie Project Presentation Movie TroyInclude Architecture i.docx
Movie Project Presentation Movie TroyInclude Architecture i.docx
 
Motivation and Retention Discuss the specific strategies you pl.docx
Motivation and Retention Discuss the specific strategies you pl.docxMotivation and Retention Discuss the specific strategies you pl.docx
Motivation and Retention Discuss the specific strategies you pl.docx
 
Mother of the Year In recognition of superlative paren.docx
Mother of the Year         In recognition of superlative paren.docxMother of the Year         In recognition of superlative paren.docx
Mother of the Year In recognition of superlative paren.docx
 
Mrs. G, a 55 year old Hispanic female, presents to the office for he.docx
Mrs. G, a 55 year old Hispanic female, presents to the office for he.docxMrs. G, a 55 year old Hispanic female, presents to the office for he.docx
Mrs. G, a 55 year old Hispanic female, presents to the office for he.docx
 
Mr. Rivera is a 72-year-old patient with end stage COPD who is in th.docx
Mr. Rivera is a 72-year-old patient with end stage COPD who is in th.docxMr. Rivera is a 72-year-old patient with end stage COPD who is in th.docx
Mr. Rivera is a 72-year-old patient with end stage COPD who is in th.docx
 
Mr. B, a 40-year-old avid long-distance runner previously in goo.docx
Mr. B, a 40-year-old avid long-distance runner previously in goo.docxMr. B, a 40-year-old avid long-distance runner previously in goo.docx
Mr. B, a 40-year-old avid long-distance runner previously in goo.docx
 
Moving members of the organization through the change process ca.docx
Moving members of the organization through the change process ca.docxMoving members of the organization through the change process ca.docx
Moving members of the organization through the change process ca.docx
 
Mr. Friend is acrime analystwith the SantaCruz, Califo.docx
Mr. Friend is acrime analystwith the SantaCruz, Califo.docxMr. Friend is acrime analystwith the SantaCruz, Califo.docx
Mr. Friend is acrime analystwith the SantaCruz, Califo.docx
 
Mr. E is a pleasant, 70-year-old, black, maleSource Self, rel.docx
Mr. E is a pleasant, 70-year-old, black, maleSource Self, rel.docxMr. E is a pleasant, 70-year-old, black, maleSource Self, rel.docx
Mr. E is a pleasant, 70-year-old, black, maleSource Self, rel.docx
 
Motor Milestones occur in a predictable developmental progression in.docx
Motor Milestones occur in a predictable developmental progression in.docxMotor Milestones occur in a predictable developmental progression in.docx
Motor Milestones occur in a predictable developmental progression in.docx
 
Most women experience their closest friendships with those of th.docx
Most women experience their closest friendships with those of th.docxMost women experience their closest friendships with those of th.docx
Most women experience their closest friendships with those of th.docx
 
Most patients with mental health disorders are not aggressive. Howev.docx
Most patients with mental health disorders are not aggressive. Howev.docxMost patients with mental health disorders are not aggressive. Howev.docx
Most patients with mental health disorders are not aggressive. Howev.docx
 
Most of our class readings and discussions to date have dealt wi.docx
Most of our class readings and discussions to date have dealt wi.docxMost of our class readings and discussions to date have dealt wi.docx
Most of our class readings and discussions to date have dealt wi.docx
 
Most people agree we live in stressful times. Does stress and re.docx
Most people agree we live in stressful times. Does stress and re.docxMost people agree we live in stressful times. Does stress and re.docx
Most people agree we live in stressful times. Does stress and re.docx
 
Most of the ethical prescriptions of normative moral philosophy .docx
Most of the ethical prescriptions of normative moral philosophy .docxMost of the ethical prescriptions of normative moral philosophy .docx
Most of the ethical prescriptions of normative moral philosophy .docx
 
Most healthcare organizations in the country are implementing qualit.docx
Most healthcare organizations in the country are implementing qualit.docxMost healthcare organizations in the country are implementing qualit.docx
Most healthcare organizations in the country are implementing qualit.docx
 
More work is necessary on how to efficiently model uncertainty in ML.docx
More work is necessary on how to efficiently model uncertainty in ML.docxMore work is necessary on how to efficiently model uncertainty in ML.docx
More work is necessary on how to efficiently model uncertainty in ML.docx
 
Mortgage-Backed Securities and the Financial CrisisKelly Finn.docx
Mortgage-Backed Securities and the Financial CrisisKelly Finn.docxMortgage-Backed Securities and the Financial CrisisKelly Finn.docx
Mortgage-Backed Securities and the Financial CrisisKelly Finn.docx
 
Moral Development  Lawrence Kohlberg developed six stages to mora.docx
Moral Development  Lawrence Kohlberg developed six stages to mora.docxMoral Development  Lawrence Kohlberg developed six stages to mora.docx
Moral Development  Lawrence Kohlberg developed six stages to mora.docx
 

Recently uploaded

Introduction to AI in Higher Education_draft.pptx
Introduction to AI in Higher Education_draft.pptxIntroduction to AI in Higher Education_draft.pptx
Introduction to AI in Higher Education_draft.pptxpboyjonauth
 
Software Engineering Methodologies (overview)
Software Engineering Methodologies (overview)Software Engineering Methodologies (overview)
Software Engineering Methodologies (overview)eniolaolutunde
 
Grant Readiness 101 TechSoup and Remy Consulting
Grant Readiness 101 TechSoup and Remy ConsultingGrant Readiness 101 TechSoup and Remy Consulting
Grant Readiness 101 TechSoup and Remy ConsultingTechSoup
 
“Oh GOSH! Reflecting on Hackteria's Collaborative Practices in a Global Do-It...
“Oh GOSH! Reflecting on Hackteria's Collaborative Practices in a Global Do-It...“Oh GOSH! Reflecting on Hackteria's Collaborative Practices in a Global Do-It...
“Oh GOSH! Reflecting on Hackteria's Collaborative Practices in a Global Do-It...Marc Dusseiller Dusjagr
 
BASLIQ CURRENT LOOKBOOK LOOKBOOK(1) (1).pdf
BASLIQ CURRENT LOOKBOOK  LOOKBOOK(1) (1).pdfBASLIQ CURRENT LOOKBOOK  LOOKBOOK(1) (1).pdf
BASLIQ CURRENT LOOKBOOK LOOKBOOK(1) (1).pdfSoniaTolstoy
 
Mastering the Unannounced Regulatory Inspection
Mastering the Unannounced Regulatory InspectionMastering the Unannounced Regulatory Inspection
Mastering the Unannounced Regulatory InspectionSafetyChain Software
 
Separation of Lanthanides/ Lanthanides and Actinides
Separation of Lanthanides/ Lanthanides and ActinidesSeparation of Lanthanides/ Lanthanides and Actinides
Separation of Lanthanides/ Lanthanides and ActinidesFatimaKhan178732
 
Presiding Officer Training module 2024 lok sabha elections
Presiding Officer Training module 2024 lok sabha electionsPresiding Officer Training module 2024 lok sabha elections
Presiding Officer Training module 2024 lok sabha electionsanshu789521
 
Industrial Policy - 1948, 1956, 1973, 1977, 1980, 1991
Industrial Policy - 1948, 1956, 1973, 1977, 1980, 1991Industrial Policy - 1948, 1956, 1973, 1977, 1980, 1991
Industrial Policy - 1948, 1956, 1973, 1977, 1980, 1991RKavithamani
 
Concept of Vouching. B.Com(Hons) /B.Compdf
Concept of Vouching. B.Com(Hons) /B.CompdfConcept of Vouching. B.Com(Hons) /B.Compdf
Concept of Vouching. B.Com(Hons) /B.CompdfUmakantAnnand
 
The Most Excellent Way | 1 Corinthians 13
The Most Excellent Way | 1 Corinthians 13The Most Excellent Way | 1 Corinthians 13
The Most Excellent Way | 1 Corinthians 13Steve Thomason
 
Employee wellbeing at the workplace.pptx
Employee wellbeing at the workplace.pptxEmployee wellbeing at the workplace.pptx
Employee wellbeing at the workplace.pptxNirmalaLoungPoorunde1
 
Arihant handbook biology for class 11 .pdf
Arihant handbook biology for class 11 .pdfArihant handbook biology for class 11 .pdf
Arihant handbook biology for class 11 .pdfchloefrazer622
 
How to Make a Pirate ship Primary Education.pptx
How to Make a Pirate ship Primary Education.pptxHow to Make a Pirate ship Primary Education.pptx
How to Make a Pirate ship Primary Education.pptxmanuelaromero2013
 
APM Welcome, APM North West Network Conference, Synergies Across Sectors
APM Welcome, APM North West Network Conference, Synergies Across SectorsAPM Welcome, APM North West Network Conference, Synergies Across Sectors
APM Welcome, APM North West Network Conference, Synergies Across SectorsAssociation for Project Management
 
Solving Puzzles Benefits Everyone (English).pptx
Solving Puzzles Benefits Everyone (English).pptxSolving Puzzles Benefits Everyone (English).pptx
Solving Puzzles Benefits Everyone (English).pptxOH TEIK BIN
 
CARE OF CHILD IN INCUBATOR..........pptx
CARE OF CHILD IN INCUBATOR..........pptxCARE OF CHILD IN INCUBATOR..........pptx
CARE OF CHILD IN INCUBATOR..........pptxGaneshChakor2
 

Recently uploaded (20)

Código Creativo y Arte de Software | Unidad 1
Código Creativo y Arte de Software | Unidad 1Código Creativo y Arte de Software | Unidad 1
Código Creativo y Arte de Software | Unidad 1
 
Introduction to AI in Higher Education_draft.pptx
Introduction to AI in Higher Education_draft.pptxIntroduction to AI in Higher Education_draft.pptx
Introduction to AI in Higher Education_draft.pptx
 
Software Engineering Methodologies (overview)
Software Engineering Methodologies (overview)Software Engineering Methodologies (overview)
Software Engineering Methodologies (overview)
 
Grant Readiness 101 TechSoup and Remy Consulting
Grant Readiness 101 TechSoup and Remy ConsultingGrant Readiness 101 TechSoup and Remy Consulting
Grant Readiness 101 TechSoup and Remy Consulting
 
“Oh GOSH! Reflecting on Hackteria's Collaborative Practices in a Global Do-It...
“Oh GOSH! Reflecting on Hackteria's Collaborative Practices in a Global Do-It...“Oh GOSH! Reflecting on Hackteria's Collaborative Practices in a Global Do-It...
“Oh GOSH! Reflecting on Hackteria's Collaborative Practices in a Global Do-It...
 
BASLIQ CURRENT LOOKBOOK LOOKBOOK(1) (1).pdf
BASLIQ CURRENT LOOKBOOK  LOOKBOOK(1) (1).pdfBASLIQ CURRENT LOOKBOOK  LOOKBOOK(1) (1).pdf
BASLIQ CURRENT LOOKBOOK LOOKBOOK(1) (1).pdf
 
Mastering the Unannounced Regulatory Inspection
Mastering the Unannounced Regulatory InspectionMastering the Unannounced Regulatory Inspection
Mastering the Unannounced Regulatory Inspection
 
Separation of Lanthanides/ Lanthanides and Actinides
Separation of Lanthanides/ Lanthanides and ActinidesSeparation of Lanthanides/ Lanthanides and Actinides
Separation of Lanthanides/ Lanthanides and Actinides
 
Presiding Officer Training module 2024 lok sabha elections
Presiding Officer Training module 2024 lok sabha electionsPresiding Officer Training module 2024 lok sabha elections
Presiding Officer Training module 2024 lok sabha elections
 
Industrial Policy - 1948, 1956, 1973, 1977, 1980, 1991
Industrial Policy - 1948, 1956, 1973, 1977, 1980, 1991Industrial Policy - 1948, 1956, 1973, 1977, 1980, 1991
Industrial Policy - 1948, 1956, 1973, 1977, 1980, 1991
 
Staff of Color (SOC) Retention Efforts DDSD
Staff of Color (SOC) Retention Efforts DDSDStaff of Color (SOC) Retention Efforts DDSD
Staff of Color (SOC) Retention Efforts DDSD
 
Model Call Girl in Tilak Nagar Delhi reach out to us at 🔝9953056974🔝
Model Call Girl in Tilak Nagar Delhi reach out to us at 🔝9953056974🔝Model Call Girl in Tilak Nagar Delhi reach out to us at 🔝9953056974🔝
Model Call Girl in Tilak Nagar Delhi reach out to us at 🔝9953056974🔝
 
Concept of Vouching. B.Com(Hons) /B.Compdf
Concept of Vouching. B.Com(Hons) /B.CompdfConcept of Vouching. B.Com(Hons) /B.Compdf
Concept of Vouching. B.Com(Hons) /B.Compdf
 
The Most Excellent Way | 1 Corinthians 13
The Most Excellent Way | 1 Corinthians 13The Most Excellent Way | 1 Corinthians 13
The Most Excellent Way | 1 Corinthians 13
 
Employee wellbeing at the workplace.pptx
Employee wellbeing at the workplace.pptxEmployee wellbeing at the workplace.pptx
Employee wellbeing at the workplace.pptx
 
Arihant handbook biology for class 11 .pdf
Arihant handbook biology for class 11 .pdfArihant handbook biology for class 11 .pdf
Arihant handbook biology for class 11 .pdf
 
How to Make a Pirate ship Primary Education.pptx
How to Make a Pirate ship Primary Education.pptxHow to Make a Pirate ship Primary Education.pptx
How to Make a Pirate ship Primary Education.pptx
 
APM Welcome, APM North West Network Conference, Synergies Across Sectors
APM Welcome, APM North West Network Conference, Synergies Across SectorsAPM Welcome, APM North West Network Conference, Synergies Across Sectors
APM Welcome, APM North West Network Conference, Synergies Across Sectors
 
Solving Puzzles Benefits Everyone (English).pptx
Solving Puzzles Benefits Everyone (English).pptxSolving Puzzles Benefits Everyone (English).pptx
Solving Puzzles Benefits Everyone (English).pptx
 
CARE OF CHILD IN INCUBATOR..........pptx
CARE OF CHILD IN INCUBATOR..........pptxCARE OF CHILD IN INCUBATOR..........pptx
CARE OF CHILD IN INCUBATOR..........pptx
 

Rethinking The Current Inflation Target Range In South Afric.docx

  • 1. Rethinking The Current Inflation Target Range In South Africa Lumengo Bonga-Bonga, Ntsakeseni Letitia Lebese The Journal of Developing Areas, Volume 53, Number 2, Spring 2019, pp. 13-27 (Article) Published by Tennessee State University College of Business DOI: For additional information about this article Access provided by Ebsco Publishing (11 Sep 2018 13:19 GMT) https://doi.org/10.1353/jda.2019.0018 https://muse.jhu.edu/article/702993 https://doi.org/10.1353/jda.2019.0018 https://muse.jhu.edu/article/702993 T h e J o u r n a l o f D e v e l o p i n g A r e a s Volume 53 No. 2 Spring 2019 RETHINKING THE CURRENT INFLATION TARGET RANGE IN SOUTH AFRICA
  • 2. Lumengo Bonga-Bonga Ntsakeseni Letitia Lebese University of Johannesburg, South Africa ABSTRACT Critics argue that inflation targeting is not an appropriate monetary policy framework for developing countries. They maintain that developing countries are more susceptible to the negative effects of external shocks due to the uncertainty perceived by investors with respect to their political and economic stability. It is in this line that this paper assesses whether the 3%-6% inflation target is the optimal inflation target band in South Africa. To determine the optimal level of inflation target in South Africa, this paper follows the methodology developed by Ball and Mankiw (2002), which rests on the premise that there is a short run trade-off between inflation and unemployment. Ball and Mankiw (2002) show that there exists a level of unemployment that is consistent with stable inflation. The unemployment level that
  • 3. corresponds with a stable inflation is known as the non-accelerating inflation rate of unemployment (NAIRU). Thus, this paper uses an expectations-augmented Phillips curve to estimate a time- varying NAIRU for South Africa from 1980 to 2015. We use the headline inflation rate and the official unemployment rate based on the narrow definition to evaluate the appropriateness of the current inflation target range. Quarterly data from 1980 to 2015 sourced from Quantec is used to this end. The results of the empirical analysis indicate that, if South Africa were to put in place an inflation target range based on the NAIRU, it would have to target an inflation rate that ranges from 1.4 to 11.5 percent. This range is different to the official inflation target of 3% to 6% adopted by the South African Reserve Bank (SARB). Furthermore, this paper finds that the Phillips curve is not vertical in South Africa, as actual inflation does not depend solely on inflation expectations. The policy implication of the findings of this paper is that the South African Reserve Bank should think about revising its current inflation target, as it is too narrow for an emerging economy.
  • 4. The current low range of inflation target could have a negative effect on output and unemployment in the country. This paper recommends that the SARB should rely on the realities of the South African economy rather than on external concerns when defining the range of inflation target. JEL Classifications: E52, C13 Keywords: inflation target, NAIRU, unemployment, South Africa Corresponding Authors’ Email Addresses: [email protected] INTRODUCTION South Africa had double-digit inflation rates from the 1970s to the early 1990s (Casteleijn 1999; Rossouw & Padayachee, 2008). In 1994, following its re-integration into the international economy, South Africa was subjected to increased political pressure to reduce its inflation rate to levels which were commensurate with its trading partners (Banerjee, Galioni, Levinsohn, McLaren & Woolard 2008; van der Merwe 2004; Padayachee, 2001; Ricci, 2005). Subsequently, the government
  • 5. introduced inflation targeting as a monetary policy framework in 2000 (Mboweni 1999) Inflation targeting policy aimed at stabilising prices in South Africa. A number of studies support the view 14 that the pursuit of price stability has been successful in reducing the high inflation rate in South Africa (National Labour and Economic Development Institute, 2004 Ricci, 2005). South Africa managed to achieve single digit inflation rates in the mid-1990s for the first time since the 1960s, (Casteleijn, 1999). However, while the South African Reserve Bank (SARB) succeeded in reducing inflation, the government failed to realise the development objectives as set out in GEAR (National Labour and Economic Development Institute, 2004). South Africa experienced a continued increase in the unemployment rate from 1980 to 2010, reaching 27% in 2003 (Department of Economic
  • 6. Development, 2010). In 2010, South Africa was ranked amongst the top 10 countries in the world that have high unemployment rates (Department of Economic Development, 2010). According to McCord and Bhorat (2003), South Africa has the highest unemployment rates compared to other emerging countries in Africa, Asia and Latin America. The rising unemployment may be attributed to the change in monetary policy as international empirical evidence (Akerlof, Dickens, Perry, Gordon & Mankiw 1996; Fortin, 2001; Lundborg & Sacklẻn, 2006) indicates that a change in the inflation rate from a high level to a low level is associated with perpetual increases in the unemployment rate. Some experts reinforce this observation by noting that at low inflation rates, the Phillips curve is negatively sloped, implying a trade-off between inflation and unemployment (Akerlof et al., 1996; Holden, 2002; Lundborg and Sacklẻn, 2006; Padayachee, 2001). The existence of trade-off means that reductions in the
  • 7. inflation rate are directly correlated with increases in the unemployment rate (Erceg, 2002). Hence, it is essential for a central bank to establish the correct shape of the Phillips curve for that particular economy and the consequent dynamics of the inflation/unemployment trade-off before deciding, on the one hand, on the suitable monetary policy regime to pursue or, on the other, if inflation targeting is the choice, on the targeted band. Critics argue that inflation targeting is not an appropriate monetary policy framework for developing countries (Kahn, 2008). They maintain that developing countries are more susceptible to the negative effects of external shocks due to the uncertainty perceived by investors with respect to their political and economic stability (Ricci, 2005). Investor uncertainty and the requirement of a flexible foreign exchange market expose small developing economies to negative external shocks more than it does
  • 8. big and developed economies (Kahn, 2008; Ricci, 2005). In addition, some scholars argue that if the central bank makes the pursuit of price stabilisation its sole objective, economic growth and development are inhibited (Kahn, 2008). However, recent studies (Arkerlof, Dickens, Perry, Bewley and Blinder, 2000; Ball and Mankiw, 2002; Fortin, 2001; Lundborg and Sacklẻn, 2006; Hsing, 2009; Fortin, 2001), on the relationship between inflation and unemployment indicate that there is a particular point on a non- linear Phillips curve where the trade-off is optimised and central banks should set the target for inflation at this specific point. Since a number of authors suggest that inflation targeting derives its justification from the theory of natural rate (Bernanke, et al., 1999; Bernanke, 2003), it is clear that the optimal target for inflation rate should be set by taking into account the level of natural rate of unemployment, which determines the shape of the Phillips curve. However, the widespread implementation of low-inflation
  • 9. targets assumes, without proper verification, the principle of a vertical long-run Phillips curve, whereby inflation has no long-run effect on unemployment. This paper shows that 15 setting inflation targets simply by relying on the idea of vertical Phillips curve may be misleading if the actual shape of the Phillips curve is not vertical. Given the fact that unemployment has maintained a growing trend in South Africa even after the adoption of the inflation targeting policy, the policy has become very controversial (Department of Economic Development, 2010; Banerjee, Galioni, Levinsohn, McLaren & Woolard, 2007; Klasen & Woolard, 2008), this paper aims to evaluate whether the 3%-6% inflation target band is at a level that optimised the trade-off between inflation and unemployment. An optimal inflation ban should refrain from generating excess unemployment. The remainder of this paper is
  • 10. organised as follows: In Section 2, the literature is reviewed. This is followed by the discussion of methodology in Section 3. The estimation of results is detailed in section 4 while in section 5 we provide the conclusion and policy implications of the research. LITERATURE REVIEW Theoretical Discussion The debate on the relationship between inflation and unemployment dates back to 1958 when Phillips (1958) found a nonlinear relationship between unemployment and changes in wages by conducting empirical tests on data from the United Kingdom for the period 1861 to 1951. Based on the results of his study, Phillips concluded that by accepting some degree of inflation, central banks could maintain lower rates of unemployment (Van der Merwe, 2004). Phillips’ conclusion led to major disagreements among economists on the existence of a relationship between inflation
  • 11. and unemployment and, consequently, the actions that should be taken to address the trade-off between these economic indicators (Friedman, 1968; Burger and Marinkov, 2006; Fischer, 1996; Mankiw, 2001). Monetary economists argue that the Phillips curve is vertical in the long run (Friedman, 1968; Fischer, 1996; Michie, 2003). According this group of economists, the trade-off between inflation and unemployment is temporary and mainly results from the behaviour of workers as they adjust their wage expectations following an increase in the unemployment rate (Hodge, 2002; Friedman, 1968). In the long run, following the full incorporation of inflation expectations in wage negotiations; there is an increase in the inflation rate and the unemployment rate remains unchanged as nominal wages adjust towards their real rate (Hodge, 2002). The unemployment rate thus returns to its natural rate and hence, remains stable in the long run (Friedman, 1968:8 and Michie, 2003). A
  • 12. vertical Phillips curve, as hypothesised by the monetarists, implies that there is no permanent relationship between inflation and unemployment. Post-Keynesian economists contest this tenet of monetary economists. They are of the view that workers base their wages on adaptive expectations; and that a trade-off between inflation and unemployment depends on how quickly workers adopt their future inflation expectations following disturbances in the economy and on the bargaining power of employers during wage negotiations (Holden, 2002; Michie, 2003; Hodge, 2002 and Michie, 2003). The post- Keynesian economists maintain that at any unemployment rate, besides the natural rate of unemployment, there will be a trade-off between inflation and unemployment (Michie, 2003). The debate between the Keynesian, monetary and post- Keynesian economists can 16
  • 13. only be resolved by evaluating empirical evidence to conclude whether or not there is a relationship between inflation and unemployment or whether the Phillips curve is vertical or not. The empirical evidence is presented below. INTERNATIONAL EMPIRICAL EVIDENCE Existence of a Trade-Off Empirical evidence supports the existence of a trade-off between inflation and unemployment. Research-conducted for European countries (Holden, 2002); certain member countries of the Organisation for Economic Corporation and Development (Ball, Mankiw & Nordhaus, 1999) as well as for the United States of America (Karanassou, Sala & Snower, 2010; Banarjee et al., 2008; Akerlof et al., 2000)- demonstrates that there is a trade-off between inflation and unemployment. The trade- off results from, inter alia, expectations about future inflation coupled with rigidities in nominal wages (Akerlof et
  • 14. al., 1996; Akerlof et al., 2000); regulated and highly unionised labour markets (Holden, 2002) and shocks to economies (Svenssons, 1999). In their study, Akerlof et al. (2000) find that employees’ expectations deviate from rational behaviour at low inflation levels and that workers and employers tend to ignore the impact of low inflation when they negotiate wages and prices. Akerlof et al. (2000:4) use survey data based on inflation expectations of workers and employers to determine the inflation rate and the unemployment level, which optimises the trade-off between inflation and unemployment. In contrast to models based on rational expectations; Akerlof et al. (2000) find that the Phillips curve is not vertical at low inflation levels, and that there is a trade-off between inflation and unemployment. In his study on European countries, Holden (2002) find that countries with regulated labour markets, and where the majority of workers are unionised, face a trade- off between inflation and unemployment when they target low
  • 15. inflation rates. This situation arises because, in unionised labour markets, wages can only be changed through mutual consent between employers and workers (Holden, 2002). Hence, workers and their labour unions possess bargaining power, which they can use to prevent employers from effecting cuts in nominal wages when inflation is low (Holden, 2002) The inability of employers to reduce nominal wages unilaterally means that, in the long run, increases in nominal wages lead to increases in inflation rate (Holden, 2002). Determination of an Optimal Inflation Rate The existence of a trade-off means that there is an optimal inflation target. An appropriate inflation target would ideally be close to the optimal inflation rate on a nonlinear Phillips curve. Given the presence of a trade-off, studies have been conducted in certain developed countries (Akerlof et al., 2000; Fortin, 2001; Lundborg & Sacklen, 2006;
  • 16. Maugeri, 2010; Wyplosz, 2000) to evaluate whether the inflation target is set at a level that optimises the trade-off between inflation and unemployment. For example, Fortin (2001:7) in his analysis of inflation in Canada over the period 1992 to 2002 find that the inflation target, which is set by the Bank of Canada exhibits a trade-off between inflation 17 and unemployment. While the Bank of Canada has set an inflation rate band of 1%-3%, Fortin (2001) find that an optimal inflation target band for Canada would be 2%-3%. In a study of inflation targeting policy in Sweden, Lundborg & Sacklen (2006) find that the inflation target of 2 percent, which is pursued by the European Central Bank, is not at a level that optimises the trade-off between inflation and unemployment. Lundborg & Sacklen (2006) analyse data from 1963 to 2000 and find that the trade -off would be optimised if the European Central Bank targeted an
  • 17. inflation rate of 4 percent. A similar study was conducted by Maugeri (2010) for Italy for the period 1960to2003. Maugeri (2010) finds that the inflation target of 2 percent, which is pursued by the European Central Bank, is not optimal for Italy. Maugeri notes that the inflation rate that would minimise the trade-off between inflation and unemployment in Italy is between 15% and 20% (Maugeri, 2010). Making use of survey data on inflation expectations of economic agents in regulated and unionised labour markets of France, Germany, the Netherlands and Switzerland from 1960 to 1999, Wyplosz (2000) investigates the inflation rate that optimises the trade-off of the two variables in these countries. Wyplosz finds that the 2 percent inflation target, which is pursued by the European Central Bank, results in trade-off between inflation and unemployment, that is, the low inflation target leads to the increase in unemployment in these countries. The results from Wyplosz’s study (2000) suggest that an optimal inflation rate for France,
  • 18. Germany, the Netherlands and Switzerland should be 5 percent. While an optimal inflation target range should refrain from generating excess unemployment, Mishkin and Westelius (2008) suggest that the higher the uncertainty about the inflation process, the wider should the target range be. This is true for emerging market countries, which are more vulnerable to external shocks and likely to have more uncertainty about inflation outcomes. Empirical Evidence in South Africa Most of the literature on inflation targeting in South Africa (e.g. du Plessis and Burger, 2006; Fedderke and Schaling, 2005; Nell, 2002 and Pretorius and Smal, 1994) indicates the existence of trade-off, in the short run, between inflation and unemployment or between inflation and proxies for demand effects such as marginal costs and output gaps. Early studies, which were conducted in the 1960s and 1970s, find trade-off between
  • 19. inflation and unemployment (e.g. Gallaway, Koshal and Chapin (1970); Hume (1971); Hodge (2002); du Plessis and Burger (2006)) - and between inflation and output gaps (e.g. Krogh (1967); Truu (1975); Strydom and Steenkamp (1967);du Plessis and Burger (2006)). Recent studies based on output gaps (Pretorius & Smal, 1994; Fedderke & Schaling, 2005; Nell; 2002) mainly find evidence of trade-off between inflation and output gaps. Studies, based on expectations-augmented Phillips curve of South Africa (Pretorius and Smal, 1994 and Fedderke and Schaling, 2005), find that the trade-off occurs indirectly through labour costs rather than through prices. More recent studies (Leshoro, 2012; Phiri, 2010; Gupta and Uwilingiye, 2008) demonstrate that the 3%-6% inflation target range limits the level of economic growth in South Africa. Leshoro (2012) asserts that an inflation rate greater than 4 percent has a negative effect on GDP growth rates. Gupta and Uwilingiye (2008) assert that a 3% to
  • 20. 6% inflation target range results in a welfare loss, which ranges from 0.34 percent to 0.67 percent of GDP. Phiri (2010:354) find an inflation threshold of 8 percent and concludes 18 that any inflation rate below and above the threshold will have an adverse effect on growth. Methodology To determine the optimal level of inflation target in South Africa, this paper follows the methodology developed by Ball and Mankiw (2002), which rests on the premise that there is a short run trade-off between inflation and unemployment. Given the existence of the short run trade-off, Ball and Mankiw (2002) show that there exists a level of unemployment that is consistent with stable inflation. The unemployment level that corresponds with a stable inflation is known as the non-
  • 21. accelerating inflation rate of unemployment (NAIRU) (Gordon, 1997 and Ball & Mankiw, 2002). Thus, this paper uses an expectations-augmented Phillips curve to estimate a time-varying NAIRU for South Africa from 1980 to 2015. The NAIRU is not directly observable but is estimated based on variables which are used to determine an expectations- augmented Phillips curve (see Staiger, Stock, and Watson, 1997; Boone, Giorno, Meacci, Rae, Richardson and Turner, 2003). To determine if the SARB target is set at a level that optimises the trade- off between inflation and unemployment, the estimated NAIRU is used to determine a stable inflation rate for South Africa. The inflation rate, based on the estimated NAIRU, is then compared to the inflation target range that is adopted by the South African Reserve Bank. . The short-run trade-off between inflation and unemployment can be expressed as:
  • 22. Where � represents the inflation rate; � represents the parameter which represents a constant term in the equation; and which measures how the inflation rate responds to changes in the unemployment rate. Nonetheless, the amended version of the inflation- unemployment dynamics is represented as: Where e * 2 shows that the actual inflation depends on the expected inflation and how U deviates from * U . Supply shocks, such as oil crisis and changes in the exchange rate, may affect
  • 23. also the level of inflation. Ball and Mankiw (2002:118) acknowledge that economic agents base their decisions on adaptive expectations 1 . Thus, the expectations-augmented Phillips curve, which is based on adaptive expectations, is thus presented as follows: 19 UU * 1 (3) Where �−1 represents the inflation rate observed during the previous period. The expectations-augmented Phillips curve, as represented by equation 3 above, is used as a base to derive an estimate of a time-varying NAIRU that is used to determine
  • 24. a stable inflation rate. Ball and Mankiw (2002) show that to estimate the NAIRU, Equation 3 should be rewritten as: * (4) becomes: UU (5) -hand side of Equation 5 can be computed to provide the estimate of
  • 25. * U . Ball and Mankiw (2002) suggest the use of Hodrick-Prescot (HP) filter to obtain * U , which represents the longer-term trend and , the shorter-term supply shock or cyclical movement. The inflation rate, which corresponds to the natural rate of unemployment, is estimated by imputing values for parameters derived above into Equation 4. Data and Empirical Results In this study, we use the headline inflation rate official unemployment rate based on the narrow definition ( U ) to evaluate the appropriateness of the current inflation target range. Quarterly data from 1980 to 2015 is used are sourced from Quantec. In order to estimate the NAIRU ( *
  • 26. U ) we estimate the U have a unit root, we have to test if there is a cointegrating relationship between these variables by making use of the Engel-Granger cointegration test. It is important to note that the choice of the Engle-Granger cointegration over other cointegration techniques, such as the Johansen technique, is justified by the fact the Engle-Granger cointegration technique is robust even when series are fractionally integrated or depict long memory (Gonzalo and Lee, 2000). Gonzalo and Lee (2000) show that it is very difficult to distinguish between series 20 that are fractionally integrated and those that have unit root (I(1)). By applying the Engle- Granger cointegration technique, we believe that the results obtained will be robust even
  • 27. though the series are fractionally integrated or have long memory. Moreover, Silvapulle and Podivinski (2000) indicate that modellers should not be concerned by the possibility of small departure from the condition of non-normality when using cointegration technique even in finite samples. However, the authors emphasise that ARCH and GARCH effects may be more problematic and compromise the results obtained from a cointegration technique. The results of the Engle-Granger cointegration test are reflected on Table 1. The results show that the null hypothesis of no U is rejected when inflation is an endogenous variable. The study adopts the results of the Engle-Granger cointegration test and estimated the cointegrating parameter in the relationship between unemployment and inflation. The estimation, as per Equation 1, yields a value of estimated equation is represented as:
  • 28. TABLE 1. RESULTS OF THE ENGLE-GRANGER COINTEGRATION TEST is endogenous Given the above suggestion by Silvapulle and Podivinski (2000), we need to make sure that there is no ARCH effect in the results obtained. Thus, we perform the heteroscedasticity test to examine the presence of the ARCH effect in the obtained results. Table 2 presents the results of the ARCH test for heteroscedasticity in the residual. This test aims to detect the presence of time-varying volatility or ARCH effect in the residual. The results presented in Table 2 show that the null hypothesis of no ARCH is not rejected with the F-statistics and the observed R- Squared. This indicates that the residual is homoscedastic and there is no need to account for time-varying volatility in the estimated model.
  • 29. TABLE 2. HETEROSCEDASTICITY TEST: NULL HYPOTHESIS OF NO ARCH F-Statistics 1.707 Probability 0.2001 Obs R-Squared 1.724 Probability Chi-Square 0.1892 Note: The probabilities show the rejection of the null hypothesis rate of unemployment as per the procedure described above by using the HP filter. Figure 1 below provides a diagrammatic representation of South Africa’s NAIRU, together with the headline inflation and actual unemployment rate, from 1980 to 2015. Variable z-statistic Probability -29.6342 0.0214 U -18.20813 0.2031 21
  • 30. FIGURE 1. GRAPHICAL REPRESENTATION OF SOUTH AFRICA'S ESTIMATED NAIRU, INFLATION AND UNEMPLOYMENT FROM 1980 TO 2015 Figure 1 shows that the estimated time-varying NAIRU increases substantially from single digit figures in the 1980s to double digit figures from the late 1980s to 2000. From the year 2000 to 2015, the NAIRU stabilises around 23 to 25 percent. In Kabundi et al. (2015) and Viegi (2015) we find support for these findings as both studies show that the NAIRU stabilises around these rates in South Africa. Figure 1 further shows that the unemployment rate is below the NAIRU during the period 1994 to 1997. This period corresponds to increasing economic activities in South Africa. However, the unemployment rate in South Africa trended above the NAIRU during the period 1998- 2000 marking the period of contagion from the Russian and
  • 31. Latin American financial crises and during the period post 2008, signifying the effects of global financial crisis o n the South African labour market. The trend of unemployment compared to the NAIRU is an evidence of the contribution of external shocks to the labour market and economic activities in South Africa. It is clear from Figure 1 that the relationship between inflation unemployment and NAIRU is far from supporting the evidence of a vertical Phillips curve in South Africa, especially after 2004. Figure 1 shows that deviation of unemployment rate from NAIRU translates to changes in inflation rate. For example, in the period 2004-2008 the unemployment rate in South Africa is below the NAIRU. This deviation of unemployment rate from the NAIRU coincides with the increase in inflation rate in South Africa. However, during the period of global financial crisis and the afterward of the crisis, unemployment soars above the NAIRU as inflation rate decreases.
  • 32. This finding indicates thatthe difference between the NAIRU and unemployment coincide with the change in inflation in South Africa as per the theory of the augmented Phillips curve. This occurrence indicates that actual inflation is not only influenced by inflation expectations but also by the deviation of the unemployment rate from the NAIRU. This further shows that the Phillips curve is not vertical in South Africa, as actual inflation does not depend solely on inflation expectations. The final step of the analysis is to obtain estimates of the stable inflation rate that would minimise the trade- 8 12 16 20 24 28 0 4 8
  • 33. 12 16 20 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 2005 2010 2015 inflation unemployment NAIRU 22 off between inflation and unemployment. The estimates from Equation 3 yield a rate of inflation, which ranges from 1.4 percent to 11.5 percent from 2000 to 2015. Figure 2 derived from the South African NAIRU ( InflaN ). FIGURE 2. SOUTH AFRICA'S INFLATION RANGE BASED ON ESTIMATES OF NATURAL RATE OF UNEMPLOYMENT (INFLAN) AND THE ACTUAL
  • 34. INFLATION RATE 0 4 8 12 16 20 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 2005 2010 2015 Actual inflation InflaN similar trends, but, in spite of this, they have different ranges. Moreover, these results indicate that, if South Africa were to put in place an inflation target range based on the NAIRU, it would have to target an inflation rate that ranges from 1.4 to 11.5 percent. This range is different to the official inflation target of 3% to 6% adopted by the South African Reserve Bank
  • 35. (SARB). It is a reality that when South Africa implemented inflation targeting, it chose an inflation range that coincided with its trading partners rather than a range that could optimise the trade-off between unemployment and inflation. It is clear that monetary policy makers in South Africa are adopting the inflation targeting policy on the premise of a vertical Phillips Curve without sound evaluation of the domestic context and reality. It is not surprising that stakeholders such as the trade unions continue to believe that the South African Reserve Bank has been too restrictive in the conduct of monetary policy. Although South Africa’s trading partners have set inflation targets at similarly lower rates, these countries have lower unemployment rate and NAIRU than South Africa’s which gives them the leverage to target inflation rates over narrow bands. Table 3 indicates that a vast majority of these countries have low and stable inflation rate interval, and with the exception of Brazil, all the countries, Thailand, Peru and Israel target inflation at rates which are slightly below
  • 36. South Africa’s inflation target range. It is then difficult to understand why South Africa has a lower upper bound inflation rate and a tighter inflation target interval than one of his important trade partner, Brazil. A wider inflation target, like the one of Brazil is ideal for emerging market economies that are vulnerable to external shocks. A wider inflation target range could prevent monetary authorities from frequently reacting to external shocks. Stringent anti- inflationary policies might have caused persistent and high unemployment in South Africa. Literature shows that a number of emerging market economies have harmed their economies from unnecessarily reacting to external shocks. For example, Mackowiak (2007) shows that United States (US) monetary policy shocks affect a larger fraction of 23 the variance in the aggregate price level and aggregate output in emerging economies
  • 37. than of the variances in the same variables in the US itself. Moreover, Kaminsky et al. (2005) indicate that emerging market economies are overwhelmingly procyclical in their conduct of monetary policy and often deepen downturns when reacting to external shocks. South African monetary authority may have caused reduced economic activities as it responds to the effects of external shocks on the domestic economy with restrictive measures. Indeed a number of studies have found that restrictive monetary policy reactions often fail to reduce inflation in South Africa (Bonga- Bonga and Kabundi, 2011). Moreover, in a historical perspective, the 3% to 6% inflation range adopted by the SARB is strikingly low, as Figure 1 shows that in the 1980s when South Africa had one digit unemployment rate, inflation rate was between 12% and 14%. TABLE 3. EMERGING MARKETS' SOUTH AFRICA'S COMPETITORS WHO ADOPTED INFLATION TARGETING
  • 38. Country Inflation Target range Unemployment rate Chile 2 - 4% 5.90% Israel 1 -3 % 6.20% Brazil 1.5 - 8.5% 6.50% Czech Republic 2 - 4% 7% Thailand 0.90% 0.80% Source: Levin, Natal & Piger (2004) and Fraga, Goldfajn & Minella (2003), World Bank (2015) Note: unemployment rate is for the period 2006-2010. CONCLUSIONS This paper aims to assess whether the SARB 3% to 6% inflation target range is at a rate that optimises the trade-off between inflation and unemployment. Empirical work shows
  • 39. that countries with low levels of inflation and/or whose Phillips Curve is vertical (many of which are developed economies) may adopt low inflation rate/ ranges targets. Studies also show that despite South Africa having non-vertical Phillips Curve, significant high levels of unemployment, and high-income inequality, its inflation targeting policy is modelled around a narrow inflation rate band with a lower upper bound, unlike countries at similar level of development such as Brazil. Furthermore, while South Africa’s inflation target range compares well with that of other emerging market countries, the level of unemployment in South Africa is higher than that of these emerging market countries. In this research work, we estimate the stable inflation rate based on the expectations-augmented Phillips curve for South Africa. Given the magnitude of the computed NAIRU, the estimation results provide an inflation range that is wider than the current inflation target range set by the South African Reserve Bank. The paper
  • 40. concludes that the current tighter inflation target policy in South Africa is based on unsound fundamentals and may have led to some unnecessary responses by the monetary authority to apply restrictive measures which in turn have been detrimental to output growth and reduced employment, among other things. The policy implication of this paper is that the South African Reserve Bank (SARB) should rethink the current inflation target range of 3% to 6%. Such a narrow 24 range of inflation target could have a negative effect on output and unemployment in the country given that monetary authority may be forced to apply unnecessary contractionary monetary policy. Moreover, the findings of this paper that SARB should broaden the inflation target range could even suggest that dual targets, inflation and output targets, may be appropriate for South Africa. The poor output growth that South Africa
  • 41. experiences warrants scrutiny by policymakers. ENDNOTES 1 Ehlers and Steinbach (2007) show that economic agents in South Africa make use of adaptive expectations to a certain extent in forming their expectations of future inflation. 2 It is important to note that the South African Reserve Bank (SARB) was targeting CPIX-inflation from 2000 t0 2008 instead of the headline CPI. In 2008, the SARB reverted to targeting headline CPI inflation. REFERENCES Arkerlof, GA, Dickens, WT, Perry, GL, Gordon, RJ, Mankiw, NG (1996) The macroeconomics of low inflation. Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 1999: 1 – 76. Arkerlof, GA, Dickens, WT, Perry, GL, Bewley, TF, Blinder, AS (2000) Near- Rational Wage and Price Setting and the Long-Run Phillips
  • 42. Curve. Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 2000: 1 – 60. Ball, L, Mankiw, NG, Nordhaus, WD (1999) Aggregate Demand and Long-run Unemployment. Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 1999: 189 – 251. Ball, L, Mankiw, NG (2002) The NAIRU in theory and practice. Journal of Economic Perspectives 16: 115 – 136. Banerjee, A, Galioni, S, Levinsohn, J, McLaren, Z, Woolard, I (2007) Why has unemployment risen in the new South Africa? National Bureau of Economic Research, NBER Working Paper Series, Working Paper No. 13167. Banerjee, A, Galioni, S, Levinsohn, J, McLaren, Z, Woolard, I. (2008). Why has unemployment risen in the new South Africa? Economics of Transition 16: 715 - 740. Bernanke, BS, Laubach, TS, Mishkin, FS (1999) Inflation targeting. Princeton University Press, Princeton Bernanke, BS (2003) Panel discussion, October 17. www.federalreserve.
  • 43. gov/boarddocs/speeches/2003. Accessed 12 Decembre 2015. Bonga-Bonga, L, Kabundi, A (2011) Monetary policy action and inflation in Siuth aFrica: an empirical analysis, African Finance Analysis 13: 25-37. Boone, L, Giorno, C, Meacci, M., Rae, D, Richardson, P, Turner, D (2003) Estimating the structural rate of unemployment for the OECD countries. OECD Economic Studies 2002/2: 172 - 211. Burger, P, Marinkov, M (2006) The South African Phillips curve: How applicable is the Gordon model? South African Journal of Economics 74: 172 – 189. Casteleijn, AJH (1999) The Viability of Implementing an Inflation Targeting Monetary Policy Framework in South Africa. South African Reserve Bank: Pretoria. Department of Economic Development (2010). New Growth Path Framework. Department of Economic Development: Pretoria Department of Finance (1996) Growth,
  • 44. 25 Employment and Redistribution: A Macroeconomic Strategy. Department of Finance: Pretoria. Du Plessis, S, Burger, R (2006) A New Keynesian Phillips Curve for South Africa. Paper presented at the South African Reserve Bank Conference: Pretoria. Ehler, N, Steinbach, R (2007) The formation of inflation expectations in South Africa. Working paper no. 3243, South African Reserve Bank. Erceg, CJ (2002) Choice of an Inflation Target Range in a Small Open Economy. AEA Papers and Proceedings 92: 85 – 89. Fedderke, JW, Schaling, E ( 2005) Modelling Inflation in South Africa: A multivariate cointegration analysis. South African Journal of Economics 73: 79 - 92. Fischer, S (1996) Why are central banks pursuing long-run price stability? Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City: Kansas City.
  • 45. Fortin, P, (2001) Inflation targeting: the three percent solution. Policy Matters 2: 1 – 16. Fraga, A, Goldfajn, I, Minella, A (2003) Inflation targeting in emerging market economies. National Bureau of Economic Research, NBER Working Paper Series, Working Paper No. 10019. Friedman, M, (1968) The Role of Monetary Policy. The American Economic Review 58:1 - 17. Gonzalo, J and Lee, TH (2000). On the robustness of cointegration tests when series are fractionally integrated. Journal of Applied Statistics, 27(7): 821-827. Gordon, RJ (1997) The time-varying NAIRU and its implications for economic policy. Journal of Economic Perspectives 11:11 – 32. Gupta, R, Uwilingiye, J (2008). Measuring the Welfare Cost of Inflation in South Africa. Economic Research Southern Africa, Working Paper No. 68. Hodge, D (2002) Inflation versus unemployment in South
  • 46. Africa: Is there a trade-off? South African Journal of Economics 70: 418 – 443. Holden, S (2002) The costs of price stability – downward nominal wage rigidity in Europe. The National Bureau of Economic Research, Working Paper No. 8865. Hsing, Y (2009) Estimating the time-varying NAIRU for Germany and policy implications. Applied Economic Letters 16:469 – 473. Kabundi, A, Schaling, E, Some, M (2015) Estimating a Phillips Curve for South Africa: A Bounded Random Walk Approach. ERSA working paper no. 568. Kahn, B (2008) Challenges of Inflation Targeting for Emerging- market Economies: The South African Case. Paper presented for the South African Reserve Bank Conference Series on Challenges for monetary policy-makers in emerging markets, Pretoria. Kaminsky, GL, Reinhart, CM, Vegh, CA (2005) When it rains, it pours: procyclical capital flow and macroeconomic policies, in NBER
  • 47. macroeconomic Annual 2004, Vol.19, ed. By Gertler, M. and Rogoff, K., Cambridge: NBER. Karanassou, M, Sala, H, Snower, DJ (2010) Phillips curves and unemployment dynamics: A critique and holistic perspective. Journal of Economic Perspectives 24: 1 - 51. Klasen, S, Woolard, I. (2008) Surviving Unemployment without State Support: Unemployment and Household Formation in South Africa. Journal of African Economies 18: 1 – 51. 26 Leshoro, TLA. (2012) Estimating the inflation threshold for South Africa. Economic Research Southern Africa. ERSA, Working Paper 285. Levin, AT, Natalucci, FM, Piger, JM (2004) The macroeconomics effects of inflation targeting. Conference proceeding of the 28
  • 48. th annual economic policy conference on “Inflation Targeting: Prospects and Problems” held in St Loius. Conducted by the Federal Reserve Bank of St Louis. St Louis: Federal Reserve Bank of St Louis. Lundborg, P, Sacklẻn, H (2006) Low-inflation targeting and long run unemployment. The Scandinavian Journal of Economics 108:397 – 418. Mackowiak, B (2007) External shocks, US monetary policy shocks and macroeconomic fluctuations in emerging market. Journal of monetary economics 54: 2512-2520. Mankiw, NG (2001) The Inexorable and Mysterious Trade-off between Inflation and Unemployment. The Economic Journal 111: C45 – C61. Maugeri, N (2010) Macroeconomic Implications of Near Rational Behaviour: An Application to the Italian Phillips Curve. Unpublished doctoral thesis. Siena: Università di Siena.
  • 49. Mboweni, TT (1999) Inflation targeting in South Africa. The South African Journal of Economics 67: 401 - 409. McCord, A, Bhorat, H (2003). Employment and Labour Market Trends. In: Kraak A, Perold, H (eds) Human Resources Development Review. HSRC Press: Cape Town Michie, J (2003) The Institutional Underpinnings of the Unemployment-Inflation Relationship: A Review Paper. Human Sciences Research Council: Pretoria: Mishkin, FS, Westelius, NJ (2008) Inflation Band Targeting and Optimal Inflation Contracts. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 40: 557-582 National Labour and Economic Development Institute (2004). Highlights of the current labour market conditions in South Africa. Johannesburg: National Labour and Economic Development Institute. Nell, KS (2002) Is low inflation a precondition for faster growth? The case of
  • 50. South Africa. University of Kent, Department of Economics, Working Paper No. 0011. Padayachee, V (2001) Central bank transformation in a globalized world: The Reserve Bank in post-apartheid South Africa. Journal of International Development 13: 741 – 765. Phillips, AW (1958) The Relation between Unemployment and the Rate of Change of Money Wage Rates in the United Kingdom, 1861 – 1957. Economica 25:283- 299. Phiri, A (2010) At what level is inflation least detrimental towards finance- growth activity in South Africa? Journal of Sustainable Development in Africa 12: 354 – 364. Pretorius, CJ and Smal, MM (1994) A macro-economic examination of the price-formation process in the South African economy. The South African Reserve Bank Quarterly Bulletin 191: 25 – 36.
  • 51. Ricci, LA (2005) Bringing inflation under control. In: Nowak, M, Ricci, LA (eds) Post-Apartheid South Africa: The First Ten Years. International Monetary Fund: Washington. http://ideas.repec.org/a/mcb/jmoncb/v40y2008i4p557-582.html http://ideas.repec.org/a/mcb/jmoncb/v40y2008i4p557-582.html 27 Rossouw, J, Padayachee, V (2008) An Analysis of inflation from a central banking perspective: The South African experience since 1921. University of Kwazulu Natal: School of Development Studies. Working Paper No. 50. Silvapulle, PS and Podivinsky, JM (2000). The effect of non- normal disturbances and conditional heteroskedasticity on multiple cointegration tests. Journal of Statistical Computation and Simulation, 65(1-4): 173-189 Staiger, D, Stock, JH, Watson, MW (1997) How Precise are Estimates of the Natural Rate of Unemployment? The Journal of Economic Perspectives 11: 34 – 49.
  • 52. Svenssons, LEO (1999) Price-level targeting versus inflation targeting: A free lunch? Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 31:277 – 295. Van der Merve, EJ (2004) Inflation targeting in South Africa. The South African Reserve Bank Occasional Paper No. 19. Viegi, N (2015) Labour Market and Monetary Policy in South Africa. SARB Working Paper 15/01. World Bank (2015) World Development Indicators. http://beta.worldbank.org. Accessed 27 january 2016. Wyplosz, C (2000) Do we know how low should inflation be? Conference proceeding of the first Central Banking Conference on “Why Price Stability” held in Geneva. Conducted by the European Central Bank. Geneva: Graduate Institute of International Studies. http://www.tandfonline.com/doi/abs/10.1080/009496500088119 97#.VSaJJ_mUe50
  • 53. http://www.tandfonline.com/doi/abs/10.1080/009496500088119 97#.VSaJJ_mUe50 http://beta.worldbank.org/ Copyright of Journal of Developing Areas is the property of Tennessee State University, College of Business and its content may not be copied or emailed to multiple sites or posted to a listserv without the copyright holder's express written permission. However, users may print, download, or email articles for individual use. Copyright © 2019 The Authors. Published by VGTU Press. This is an Open Access article distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution License (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/), which permits unrestricted use, distribution, and reproduction in any medium, provided the original author and source are credited.. To link to this article: https://doi.org/10.3846/btp.2019.01 VERSLAS: TEORIJA IR PRAKTIKA / BUSINESS: THEORY AND PRACTICE ISSN 1648-0627 / eISSN 1822-4202 http://btp.press.vgtu.lt 2019 20: 1–10 https://doi.org/10.3846/btp.2019.01
  • 54. To link to this article: https://doi.org/10.3846/btp.2019.01 Introduction Post global financial crises (2008) have forced countries to adopt expansionary and stimulating macroeconomic policies aiming to reduce unemployment. Some countries, such as United Kingdom, Germany, and the United States of America have become successful in lowering the unem- ployment in their labor markets. However, Spain and Italy are stuck at high rates of unemployment with rigid labor markets (Bhattarai 2016). The unemployment could be stabilized towards their natural rates by stimulating the ag- gregate demand through fiscal or monetary policies with or without some increase in price levels (Keynes 1936, Phllips 1958, Benati 2015, Blanchard 2016). Short-term economic problems, such as inflation and unemployment are among the most notable macroeco- nomic problems all the time (Al-zeaud 2014, Arshad 2014, Bhattarai 2016, Caporale and Škare 2011, Cioran 2014, Furuoka 2007, Furuoka 2008, Israel 2015, Katria et al., 2011, Kogid et al. 2011, Mahmood et al. 2013, Okafor et al. 2016, Sa’idu and Muhammad 2015, Ştefan and Bratu 2016, Thayaparan 2014, Touny 2013, Umaru and Zubairu 2012, Zaman et al. 2011, Pallis 2006, Benati 2015, Blanchard 2016). The Indonesian government started to focus on inflation when Indonesia experienced an economic shock during the transition period (1965–1969). Fortunately, the Indonesian government managed to control the inflation rate as Indonesia only had an inflation rate of below 10% in 1969 (Bank Indonesia 2004). However, the monetary crisis hit Indonesia again in 1997–1998 that resulted in the inflation rate of 58.4%. During the post-monetary crisis period, Indonesia managed to recover that caused the infla-
  • 55. tion rate to be below two digits. Further, the global financial crisis hit the global economy in 2008, but the Indonesian inflation rate remained stable. One of the likely factors of this condition is the government’ various economic rescue programs such as the tight money or contractive policy that was effective in taming the inflation rate. Besides, the Inflation Targeting Framework that was implemented by Bank Indonesia (the Indonesian central bank) since July THE CAUSALITY BETWEEN INFLATION AND UNEMPLOYMENT: THE INDONESIAN EVIDENCE Gatot SASONGKO1, Andrian Dolfriandra HURUTA2 Universitas Kristen Satya Wacana, Salatiga, Indonesia E-mails: [email protected] (corresponding author); [email protected] Received 21 June 2018; accepted 05 September 2018 Abstract. Two closely watched indicators of economic performance are inflation and unemployment. This study empirically analyzes the causality between inflation and unemployment in Indonesia during 1984 to 2017. The data were gathered from the Indonesian Central Bureau of Statistics. Methodologically, this study employed the Granger Causality test and Vector Autoregression to determine the causality between inflation and unemployment. The results show that there is a one-way causality between inflation and unemployment. The findings imply that unemployment causes inflation, but not vice versa. Next inflation and unemployment are also closely related to other determining factors, such as season, household income, and the decisions to attend school or to perform the housekeeping.
  • 56. Keywords: granger causality, inflation, unemployment, vector autoregression. JEL Classification: E600, E610. http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/ https://doi.org/10.3846/btp.2019.01 https://doi.org/10.3846/btp.2019.01 mailto:[email protected] mailto:[email protected] 2005 (Bank Indonesia 2017) and the empowerment of the Regional Inflation Monitoring Team in each local region fa- cilitated further the inflation control (Sasongko and Huruta 2018). The high inflation rate in 1965 also caused a high un- employment rate (read: stagflation). Since 1965, the unem- ployment rate has increased by 5–6% per year. However, similar to the inflation rate, the Indonesian government managed to reduce the unemployment rate to less than 10% (Bank Indonesia 2004). Every government closely monitor inflation and unemployment as the two main economic performance indicators. Statisticians combine inflation and unemployment data to develop the misery index that aims to measure the health of an economy. One of the economic principles is the short-term trade-off between inflation and unemployment. If fiscal and monetary policymakers in- crease aggregate demands and economy along the short-run aggregate demand curve, they can reduce unemployment temporarily, albeit with an increase in inflation rate. On the other hand, if monetary and fiscal policymakers reduce aggregate demands and economy along the short-run aggre- gate demand curve, they can curb inflation but also increase
  • 57. unemployment temporarily (Mankiw et al. 2013). This study aims to investigate the trade-off between in- flation and unemployment as found by Phllips (1958) espe- cially on the causality between inflation and unemployment in Indonesia during 1984 to 2017. It is clear the importance to recognize the relationship between inflation and unem- ployment when determining the macroeconomic policies for an economy. Despite the availability of several studies that examined the Phillips curve hypothesis, there is still a shortage of applied studies that investigate this hypothesis under developing countries where the majority of research has concentrated on the developed nations. The outcomes of this study may help policymakers to formulate better policies that can achieve their objectives of price stability and full employment in Indonesia. 1. Literature review Several studies have investigated the relationship between inflation and unemployment. Al-zeaud (2014) does not find a causal relationship between inflation and unemployment in Jordan because the study does not include foreign labor when measuring the unemployment level, thus inhibiting the trade-offs between these two variables in the short term. Further, Furuoka (2008) also does not find the causality between inflation and unemployment in the Philippines. The socioeconomic factors such as the output gaps likely explain the Phillips curve better in the Philippine context. In Nigeria, Umaru and Zubairu (2012) indicate that there is no causality between inflation and unemployment. The findings suggest that the Phillip curve does not apply in Nigeria and it is necessary to use the unemployment or inflation theory that is based more on the Nigerian data and situation.
  • 58. Besides studies that show no causal relationship between inflation and unemployment, Caporale and Škare (2011) demonstrate that there is a one-way causal relationship between inflation and job opportunities. Their findings, based on the study on the Organisation for Economic Co- operation and Development (OECD) countries, thus sug- gest that inflation affects job opportunities, but not the way around. This condition recommends policymakers to pay more attention to the short-term and long-term job and output growth. In Malaysia, Furuoka (2007) also finds the one-way causality between inflation and unemployment, implying that inflation leads to unemployment but not the way around. The study also demonstrates the cointegration and causal relationship between inflation and unemploy- ment in Malaysia. In other words, the results confirm the existence of the Phillips curve. Still in the same country, Kogid et al. (2011) document the one-way causality be- tween inflation and unemployment. Their findings imply that inflation causes unemployment, but not vice versa. The results also confirm the trade-off relationship between infla- tion and unemployment in Malaysia and the government needs to ensure that the economic policies will facilitate sustainable economic growth in the future. Using the US data, Ştefan and Bratu (2016) also find the one-way rela- tionship between inflation and unemployment, suggesting that inflation explains unemployment but not vice versa. Their findings suggest that policymakers should develop programs that reduce unemployment such as productive labor projects while at the same time also control inflation. Besides, the programs should focus on replacing foreign labors with local labors and on ensuring that the aggregate demands reach the optimal unemployment and inflation levels that will eventually support the long-term economic growth. The Pakistani study of Mahmood et al. (2013) demonstrate the one-way causality between inflation and
  • 59. unemployment, implying that inflation affects unemploy- ment but not the way around. The study also suggests that the Pakistani policymakers maintain the equilibrium point between inflation, unemployment, and interest rate to con- trol for economic shocks. Lack of focus on one of the three variables likely affects the economy. Still using the Pakistani data, Zaman et al. (2011) find the long-term relationship and one-way causality between inflation and unemploy- ment, denoting that inflation causes unemployment but not vice versa. The results also indicate that increasing inflation likely increases employment opportunities that eventually facilitates growth. The study empirically confirms the ex- istence of the Phillips curve in Pakistan, both in the short- term and in the long-term. Nigeria also exhibits the one-way causality between inflation and unemployment by Sa’idu 2 G. Sasongko, A. D. Huruta. The causality between inflation and unemployment: the Indonesian evidence and Muhammad (2015) that indicating inflation leads to unemployment but not the other way around. Their results recommend the joint efforts of all policymakers to restruc- ture the economy to manage price instability and improve the infrastructures. Further, Katria et al. (2011) who analyze the South Asian Association for Regional Cooperation (SAARC) countries, find a negative relationship between inflation and unem- ployment. Their results indicate that the collaboration be- tween monetary and fiscal policies manages to stabilize the business cycle. Next, the Nigerian study by Okafor et al. (2016) indicates that inflation negatively affects unemploy- ment. Their results recommend that policymakers not only rely on monetary targets but also on output targets through
  • 60. the economy deepening to maintain the optimal inflation rate and the minimal unemployment level. In a similar vein, Cioran (2014) demonstrates that inflation negatively affects unemployment in Romania and the European Union (EU). The findings suggest that inflation rate is an effective instru- ment to prevent increasing unemployment in the EU and Romania. Besides the negative results, other studies find the pos- itive relationship. For example, using the Egyptian data, Touny (2013) documents that unemployment positively affects inflation in the long run. The results recommend that policymakers implement their monetary policies to overcome the inflationary pressure regardless of the negative effects of unemployment. Further, Israel (2015) who analyzes several developed countries such as France, Germany, the UK, and the US, show the long-term posi- tive relationship between inflation and unemployment. This positive relationship is closely related to the political intervention. The condition causes two problems, namely: (1) monetary expansion on the income and wealth distribu- tion leads to the increasing gap between the poor and the rich. The increasing gap causes the labor market to be less flexible and increases unemployment, (2) monetary expan- sion causes less fluctuation but eventually increases unem- ployment. Using the Uni European Countries data, Pallis (2006) investigated the relationship between inflation and unemployment in the 10 new European Union countries find that in almost all countries the interaction between the price inflation rate and the unemployment level took place in a rather long time period, reaching in some cases the lag of year four. In Pakistan, Ul-Haq et al. (2012) provided further support for the existence of a long-term relationship between unemployment and inflation. On the other hand, the outcomes of VECM revealed a positive and significant correlation between inflation and unemployment either in
  • 61. the long term or the short term. Other studies demonstrate the two-way causality be- tween inflation and unemployment. For example, Arshad (2014) shows the two-way causality between inflation rate and unemployment in Pakistan, implying that inflation causes unemployment, and unemployment causes infla- tion. The data suggest that inflation rate explains the vari- ance of unemployment better than economic growth while unemployment contributes to the variance of inflation more than economic growth. In Sri Lanka, Thayaparan (2014) finds the two-way causality between inflation and unem- ployment, implying that inflation causes unemployment and unemployment causes inflation. The findings indicate that both unemployment and inflation significantly affect the Sri Lankan macroeconomic conditions. Next Bhattarai (2016) finds bidirectional causality as well as cointegrating relationships between unemployment and inflation among the OECD countries. Estimates of a vector autoregression (VAR) model on these trade-offs also support such hypoth- esis. Overall, these studies show varying results such as one-way causality, two-way causality, and no causal rela- tionship between inflation and unemployment. Further, these studies also use different analytical models, such as Granger Causality, Johansen Cointegration, Autoregressive Distributive Lag, Error Correction Model, Vector Error Correction Model, Panel Data, Vector Autoregression, and etc. It can be concluded from the previous discussion that there is an uncertain relationship between inflation and unemployment of different economies in the certain period. 2. Research methods
  • 62. This study uses the secondary data from the central bu- reau of statistics and the world bank publication. More specifically, the study relied on the time-series data from 1984 to 2017. Further Granger Causality and Vector Autoregression used to analyze the data. Before running the Granger Causality and Vector Autoregression model, this study initially ran the stationary and the lag length test. The following are the models for the stationary test and the test statistic (Brooks 2008). ΔYt = ϕYt – 1 + ϕt; (1) . (2) After running the stationary test, this study ran the lag length test. There are various approaches to select the opti- mal lag length, such as Likelihood Ratio, Final Prediction Error, Akaike Information Criterion and Schwarz Information Criterion (Rosadi 2012). This study uses the Akaike Information Criterion (AIC). The minimum value of the AIC suggests the optimal lag (Ivanov and Kilian 2005). After completing the lag length test, this study ran the Granger Causality test (Rosadi 2012): (3) Business: Theory and Practice, 2019, 20: 1–10 3 (4) The above equation indicates that Xt is inflation, and Yt is unemployment, while μt and Vt are error terms that
  • 63. are assumed to contain no serial correlation and m = n = r = s. The Granger Causality test produces four possible results as represented by the following equations: 1. If Σaj ≠ 0 and Σbj = 0, then there is a one-way causality from inflation to unemployment. 2. If Σaj = 0 and Σbj ≠ 0, then there is a one-way causality from unemployment to inflation. 3. If Σaj = 0 and Σbj = 0, then there is no causal re- lationship between inflation and unemployment. 4. If Σaj ≠ 0 and Σbj ≠ 0, then there is a two-way causality between inflation and unemployment. Further, this study ran the Vector Autoregression after completing the Granger Causality test. The Vector Autoregression (VAR) is commonly used for forecast- ing systems of interrelated time series and for analyz- ing the dynamic impact of random disturbances on the system of variables. The reduced form VAR approach sidesteps the need for structural modeling by treating every endogenous variable in the system as a function of p-lagged values of all of the endogenous variables in the system. The following is the equation in the Vector Autoregression (p) with k-endogen variable yt = (y1t , y2t , …,ykt) (Lütkepohl 2006). yt = A1yt–1 + … + Apyt–p + Cxt + ∈ t , (5) where: yt = (y1t , y2t ,…,ykt)′ is a k × 1 vector of endogenous variables; xt = (x1t , x2t ,…,xdt)′ is a d × 1 vector of exogenous
  • 64. variables; A1, …, Ap are k × k matrices of lag coefficients to be estimated; C is a d × k matrix of exogenous variable coefficients to be estimated; ∈ t = (∈ 1t , ∈ 2t , …, ∈ kt)′ is a k × 1 white noise innova- tion process, with E(∈ t) = 0, E(∈ t ∈ t′) = ∑∈ , and E(∈ t ∈ s′) = 0 for t ≠ s. 3. Results Table 1 below shows the results of the stationarity test using the Augmented Dickey-Fuller (ADF) method. Table 1 indicates that inflation is stationary at the order of integration of level or I(0) while the unemployment level Table 1. Stationarity test Variable p-value Conclusion Inflation 0.0000* I(0) Unemployment 0.3012 the series is not stationary DUnemployment** 0.0000* I(1) *indicates the rejection of the null hypothesis at 5% of significance level. ** DUnemployment implies that Unemployment at the first diffe- rence [I(1)]. Table 2. Lag length test
  • 65. Lag LogL LR FPE AIC SC HQ 0 –151.4651 NA 197.5714 10.96179 11.05695 10.99088 1 –150.5083 1.708562 245.9338 11.17917 11.46464 11.26644 2 –145.1985 8.723246 225.3365 11.08561 11.56140 11.23106 3 –125.0476 30.22635* 72.08667* 9.931972* 10.59807* 10.13561* 4 –121.2335 5.176270 74.94396 9.945251 10.80167 10.20707 5 –120.3520 1.070367 97.66239 10.16800 11.21473 10.48800 *indicates the optimal lag. is not stationary at the order of integration of level, prompt- ing us to have the first difference technique. The order 1 or I(1) differencing shows that DUnemployment does not contain the unit root anymore because it is now stationary. Further, determine the optimal length of lag by using Lag Length Test as can be seen in Table 2. Table 2 suggests the optimal lag to indicate the depen- dence of a variable on its lagged value and other endogenous variables is lag 3, implying that we have to use lag 3 to inves- tigate the causality between inflation and DUnemployment. This decision is indicated by the Akaike Information Criterion (AIC) value of 9.931972 that is smaller than the AIC values at the other lags. After ran the lag length test, this study ran the Granger Causality test using lag 3. The results of Granger Causality test can be seen in Table 3. Table 3 reveals that the null hypothesis proposing that DUnemployment does not Granger Cause infla- tion is rejected, implying that DUnemployment exhibits the Granger Cause on inflation. The results suggest that DUnemployment granger cause inflation, but not vice 4 G. Sasongko, A. D. Huruta. The causality between inflation
  • 66. and unemployment: the Indonesian evidence versa. The decision of rejecting the null hypothesis is based on the probability value of 2.E-08 that is lower than α = 5%. After ran the Granger Causality, this study ran the Vector Autoregression. Variables in a Vector Autoregression model are determined simultaneously and rely more on historic patterns of data to establish relations between unemployment and inflation than economic theories (Bhattarai 2016). The results of Vector Autoregression can be seen in Table 4. Table 4 indicates that a simple Vector Autoregression model with three lags on inflation and DUnemployment shows that Inflation is significantly influenced by DUnem- ployment(–2), DUnemployment(–3) and inflation(–1). It implies that the influence of DUnemploy ment(–2), DUnem- ployment(–3) and inflation(–1) have a large contribution to the movement of inflation in Indonesia. Estimates of Vector Autoregression also support by the Impulse Response Functions (IRFs). The results of the Impulse Response Functions (IRFs) can be seen in Figure 1. Impulse Response Functions (IRFs) was calculated for DUnemployment and inflation to address the reaction of the economy to external changes (shocks). The results of the IRFs analysis show that there is a trade-off between inflation and DUnemployment as shown by the IRFs of DUnemployment to inflation. Overall, estimate results of Granger Causality, Vector Autoregression, and Impulse Response Functions (IRFs) prove that the DUnemployment is more instrumental to explain inflation in Indonesia.
  • 67. Further, this result is supported by Touny (2013) who finds the positive effect of unemployment on inflation. The normalized cointegration equation reveals that unemploy- ment gap has a long-run positive effect on the changes in the inflation rate, which is consistent with “Lucas Critique” where a policy of inflation would fail to reduce the unem- ployment rate in the long run, because workers would eventually adjust their expectations of inflation. Further, the more rapid the reduction in the unemployment rate, the less disinflation is achieved at each unemployment rate level. Even at the cases where the unemployment rate is very high, the inflation rate falls little and thus the economy is moving too rapidly out of the recession (Pallis 2006). Other findings by Ul-Haq et al. (2012) also suggest that policy makers should pay special attention to this relationship between inflation and unemployment when they are going to design macroeconomic policies. Thus, when inflation does not support DUnemployment, it is necessary to analyze factors that affect DUnemployment. Table 5 below presents the information on the number of Table 3. Granger causality test Pairwise Granger Causality Tests Sample: 1984 2017 Lags: 3 Null Hypothesis: Obs F-Statistic Prob. Inflation does not Granger Cause DUnemployment 30 0.72869 0.5454 Dunemployment does not Granger Cause Inflation 33.0657 2.E- 08 Table 4. VAR Model of inflation and DUnemployment for Indonesia (1984–2017)
  • 68. DUnemployment Inflation Coefficients t-prob Coefficients t-prob DUnemployment(–1) –0.135523 0.20747 0.709939 1.30180 DUnemployment(–2) –0.181229 0.20753 –6.937364 1.30223 DUnemployment(–3) 0.217161 0.24175 11.60203 1.51692 Inflation(–1) 0.024945 0.01742 0.421936 0.10934 Inflation(–2) 0.003714 0.01524 0.042180 0.09564 Inflation(–3) –0.006079 0.01513 0.021545 0.09495 Constant –0.186910 0.34132 4.400302 2.14168 R2 0.124570 0.813392 F-statistic 0.545466 16.70883 Log-likehood –39.33832 –94.43436 AIC 3.089221 6.762290 Swarz SC 3.416167 7.089236 Business: Theory and Practice, 2019, 20: 1–10 5 Figure 1. Impulse responses to DUnemployment and inflation shocks Table 5. The Population 15 Years of age or over by the main employment status (2001–2017) (source: Badan Pusat Statistik (2017a), processed)) Number Main Employment Status 2001 2017 Amount % Amount % 1 Self-employed 17,451,704 19.22 21,849,573 17.54 2 Employer Assisted by Temporary/ Unpaid Worker 20,329,073
  • 69. 22.39 21,275,899 17.08 3 Employer Assisted by Permanent/ Paid Worker 2,788,878 3.07 4,446,024 3.57 4 Employee 26,579,000 29.27 47,420,633 38.08 5 Casual Agricultural Worker 3,633,126 4.00 5,360,306 4.30 6 Casual Non-Agricultural Worker 2,439,035 2.69 6,021,760 4.84 7 Family/ Unpaid Worker 17,586,601 19.37 18,164,654 14.59 8 No Answer – – – – Total 90,807,417 100.00 124,538,849 100.00 the population 15 years of age or over who worked by the main employment status. Table 5 indicates the sharp increase in the number of the working-age population with the employee status, both in absolute and relative terms. The number of employees in 2001 was 26,579,000 or 29.7% of the total working age population. The number increased to 47,420,633 or 38.08% of the total working age population in 2017. Increased in- vestment mainly drives the increasing number of employ- ees. Djambaska and Lozanoska (2015), Yelwa et al. (2015), Touny (2013), Israel (2015), Ul-Haq et al. (2012), Bhattarai (2016), and Pallis (2006) support the results by arguing that 6 G. Sasongko, A. D. Huruta. The causality between inflation and unemployment: the Indonesian evidence
  • 70. investment is a determining factor in reducing unemploy- ment. Further, another factor that affects the number of un- employment is the industry in which the population work. Table 6 below shows the data on the population 15 years of age or over who worked by industry. The proportion of the population above 15 years who worked at the primary sectors (agriculture, plantation, forestry, hunting, and fishery) declined sharply. In 1991, 53.29% of the working population worked in the primary sectors, and proportion declined to 31.74% in 2016. The agricultural sector dominates the primary sectors because of most population work in this sector (Thayaparan 2014, Yelwa et al. 2015, Kebschull 1987, Israel 2015). Edelman (2013) confirms the findings by suggesting that farmers in Latin America and Indonesia live in communities with exclusive land rights and most of them use the lands for agricultural activities. The agricultural works in Indonesia are heavily affected by the season factor, especially before 2005 because of the less developed irrigation system. More specifically, the agricultural sector greatly depends on the sufficient availability of rainfall. Farmers begin to culti- vate their soils after rain falls. Rain usually starts to fall in October and the dry season starts in April. The following Table 6 displays the open unemployment level based on the February and August surveys. February is in the rainy season while August is in the dry season. The open unem- ployment rate was higher in August, a month in the dry season than in February, a rainy month. The average August unemployment rate was 8,599,944 while in February the average unemployment level was 8,599,676. The propor-
  • 71. tion of the population working in the agricultural sector was so high that the season factor significantly affected the unemployment rate. However, the annual difference of the unemployment level between these two months tended to decline. There was even no difference of the open unemploy- ment level between February and August in 2017 (Badan Pusat Statistik 2017d). Further estimates of an Independent Sample T Test also support the data. Estimate results can be seen in Table 7. The significance value (2 tailed) of 1.000 is bigger than the tolerance value of 5% (0.05) implies that there is no difference between February and August unemployment rate. The more developed irrigation system reduce the farm- ers’ dependence on rainfall and eventually on the season. Next, the Indonesian working-age population who attended Table 6. Population 15 years of age or over who worked by main industry (1991–2016) (source: Badan Pusat Statistik (2017b), processed)) Number Main Industry 1991 2016 Amount % Amount % 1 Agriculture, Plantation, Forestry, Hunting, and Fisheries 39,385,946 53.29 38,291,111 31.74 2 Mining and Quarrying 551,581 0.75 1,311,834 1.09 3 Manufacturing Industry 7,712,468 1.43 15,975,086 1.24 4 Electricity, Gas, and Water 148,480 0.20 403,824 0.33 5 Construction 2,415,002 3.27 7,707,297 6.39 6 Trade, Restaurants, and Accomodation Services 11,190,391 1.14 28,495,436 23.62 7 Transportation, Warehousing, and Communication 2,475,803 3.35 5,192,491 4.30
  • 72. 8 Financial, Real Estate, and Business Services 515,401 0.70 3,481,598 2.89 9 Community, Social, and Personal Services 9,377,036 12.69 19,789,020 1.40 10 Undefined 139,516 0.19 – – Total 73,911,624 100.00 120,647,697 100.00 Table 7. Independent Sample T Test for Unemployment on February and August (1986–2017) Levene’s Test for Equality of Variances t-test for Equality of Means F Sig. t Df Sig. (2-tailed) Mean Difference Std. Error Difference 95% Confidence Interval of the Difference Lower Upper Unmpl Equal variances assumed
  • 73. .002 .967 .000 24 1.000 –268.00000 6.06551E5 –1.25213E6 1.25159E6 Equal variances not assumed .000 23.945 1.000 –268.00000 6.06551E5 –1.25228E6 1.25174E6 Business: Theory and Practice, 2019, 20: 1–10 7 school or performed the housekeeping increased. The num- ber of economically inactive women due to housekeeping increased both in absolute and relative terms (Ehrenberg and Smith 2012). In 2005, the number of the working age population who performed the housekeeping (mostly wom- en) was 17,275,478 or 17.08% of the total labor force. The number increased to 36,078,772 or 18.78% of the labor force in 2017 (Badan Pusat Statistik 2017c). The estimates of an Independent Sample T Test also support the data. Estimate results can be seen in Table 8. The significance value (2 tailed) of 0.000 is lower than the tolerance value of 5% (0.05) implies that there is a difference between the Indonesian working-age population who at- tended school and performed the housekeeping. Ehrenberg and Smith (2012) confirm the data by arguing that women spend a significant portion of their time to housekeeping such as cooking or taking care of their children. Women prefer housekeeping to enter the labor market because housekeeping is also a productive activity. Further, the number of the population 15 years of age
  • 74. or over who attended school increased from 9,147,830 in 2005 to 15,244,852 in 2017. However, the proportion of the working-age population who attended school decreased from 9.04% in 2005 to 7.94% in 2017. Higher school atten- dance decreases the number of unemployment. Hubacek et al. (2007) support the findings by demonstrating that the economic success of the developing Asian countries enhances the quality of life of their population. Most Asian population experience the transition from poverty to suf- ficient fulfillment of food and clothes. Further, they aspire to not only meet their basic needs of food and clothes, but also to enjoy a higher quality of life from highly nutritious food, life comfort, medical treatments, and other highly qualified services. Conclusions This study suggests the one-way relationship between inf- lation and DUnemployment. More specifically, the Granger Causality, Vector Autoregression, and Impulse Response Functions (IRFs) model show that from 1984 to 2017, DUnemployment causes inflation, but not vice versa. The results imply that the Phillips model (Phllips 1958) that proposes the reciprocal relationship between inflation and unemployment is not empirically supported in Indonesia. These findings also different with the most recently by Blanchard (2016) who find that The US Phillips curve is alive and well (or at least as well as it has been in the past). Various factors affect the Indonesian unemployment rate, such as: (1) The season factor significantly affects un- employment, albeit with the declining magnitude, because the agricultural sector still absorbs a significant portion of the Indonesian labor force; (2) Increased income encour- ages young labor force (15–19 years) to delay entering the
  • 75. labor market but to continue their studies; and (3) Better economic condition also increases the number of non-labor force. More specifically, women prefer becoming house- wives (caring for their households) in entering the labor market because caring for households is also a productive activity (Ehrenberg and Smith 2012). Inflation is a less effective policy instrument to over- come the unemployment problem in Indonesia. This ar- gument implies that increasing the inflation rate is inef- fective to reduce the unemployment rate. Numerous facts indicate that other variables affect the Indonesian unem- ployment rate. However, it is viable to increase the unem- ployment rate to control inflation, although this policy has to be implemented carefully. Further, the Indonesian geographical condition that consists of thousands of is- lands likely causes the implementation of macro policies to take a longer time because of the greater needs to adjust for the inter-region differences. Thus, the use of the panel data model likely accounts for the possible inter-region variances better. References Al-zeaud H (2014) The trade-off between unemployment and inflation evidence from causality test for Jordan. International Journal of Humanities and Social Science 4 (4): 103-111. Table 8. Independent Sample T Test for Working Age Between Attend School and Housekeeping (1986–2017) Levene’s Test for Equality of Variances t-test for Equality of Means
  • 76. F Sig. T df Sig. (2-tailed) Mean Difference Std. Error Difference 95% Confidence Interval of the Difference Lower Upper WorkAge Equal varian- ces assumed 4.160 .046 –48.096 60 .000 –9.88226 .20547 –10.29326 – 9.47126 Equal va- riances not assumed –48.096 51.170 .000 –9.88226 .20547 –10.29472 –9.46980 8 G. Sasongko, A. D. Huruta. The causality between inflation and unemployment: the Indonesian evidence Arshad I (2014) Examining relationship between
  • 77. macroeconomic variables using Var Approach. In: Proceedings of the 2014 International Conference on Industrial Engineering and Operations Management. Bali, 2393-2401 http://ieomsociety. org/ieom2014/pdfs/510.pdf Badan Pusat Statistik (2017a) Penduduk 15 Tahun Ke Atas Menurut Status Pekerjaan Utama 1986–2017 https://www. bps.go.id/statictable/2009/04/16/971/penduduk-15-tahun-ke- atasmenurut-%0Astatus-pekerjaan-utama-1986---2017.html Badan Pusat Statistik (2017b) Penduduk 15 Tahun Ke Atas yang Bekerja menurut Lapangan Pekerjaan Utama 1986–2017 https://www.bps.go.id/statictable/2009/04/16/970/penduduk- 15-tahun-ke-atas-yang-bekerja-menurut-lapangan-pekerjaan- utama-1986---2017.html Badan Pusat Statistik (2017c) Penduduk Berumur 15 tahun ke atas menurut jenis kegiatan tahun 1986–2017 https://www.bps. go.id/statictable/2009/04/16/969/penduduk-berumur-15-ta- hun-ke-atas-menurut-jenis-kegiatan-tahun-1986---2017.html Badan Pusat Statistik (2017d) Tingkat Pengangguran Terbuka (TPT) Menurut Provinsi, 1986–2017 https://www.bps.go.id/ statictable/2014/09/15/981/tingkat-pengangguran-terbuka- tpt-menurut-provinsi-1986---2017.html Bank Indonesia (2004) Laporan Perekonomian Indonesia Tahun 1998/1999. Jakarta. https://www.bi.go.id/id/publikasi/laporan- tahunan/perekonomian/Pages/LapTah 1998 1999.aspx Bank Indonesia (2017) Tujuan Kebijakan Moneter Bank In- donesia http://www.bi.go.id/id/moneter/tujuan-kebijakan/ Contents/Default.aspx
  • 78. Benati L (2015) The long-run Phillips curve: A structural VAR investigation. Journal of Monetary Economics 76: 15-28. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jmoneco.2015.06.007 Bhattarai K (2016) Unemployment-inflation trade-offs in OECD countries. Economic modelling 58 (2016): 93-103. https://doi. org/10.1016/j.econmod.2016.05.007 Blanchard O (2016) The Phillips curve: Back to the ’60s? Ameri- can Economic Review 106 (5): 31-34. https://doi.org/10.1257/ aer.p20161003 Brooks C (2008) Introductory econometrics for finance (2nd ed) Cambridge University Press. https://doi.org/10.1017/ CBO9780511841644 Caporale GM, Škare M (2011) Short- and long-run linkages between employment growth, inflation and output growth : evidence from a large panel. Economic and Finance Wor- king Paper. London https://www.brunel.ac.uk/__data/assets/ pdf_file/0011/127487/1117.pdf Cioran Z (2014) Monetary policy, inflation and the causal relation between the inflation rate and some of the macroeconomic variables. Procedia Economics and Finance 16 (May): 391- 401. https://doi.org/10.1016/S2212-5671(14)00818-1 Djambaska E, Lozanoska A (2015) Foreign direct investment and unemployment evidence from the republic of Macedonia. International Journal of Economics, Commerce and Mana- gement United Kingdom, III(12): 73-85. Edelman M (2013) What is a peasant? What are peasantries? A
  • 79. Briefing paper on issues of definition. Intergovernmental Wor- king Group on a United Nations Declaration on the Rights of Peasants and Other People Working in Rural Areas, Geneva, 15-19 July 2013. Geneva http://www.ohchr.org/Documents/ HRBodies/HRCouncil/WGPleasants/MarcEdelman.pdf Ehrenberg RG, Smith RS (2012) Modern Labor Economics: Theory and Public Policy (Donna Battista, Ed) (11th ed) Boston: Pearson Education, Inc. http://fac.ksu.edu.sa/sites/ default/files/Modern_labor_economics__theory_and_pub- lic_policy_0.pdf Furuoka F (2007) Does the “Phillips curve” really exist? New empirical evidence from Malaysia. Economics Bulletin 5 (16): 1-14. http://economicsbulletin.vanderbilt.edu/2007/volume5/ EB-07E20006A.pdf Furuoka F (2008) Unemployment and Inflation in the Philippines: new evidence from Vector Error Correction Model. Philippo- ne Journal of Development XXXV (1): 93-106. https://dirp4. pids.gov.ph/ris/pjd/pidspjd08-1unemployment.pdf Hubacek K, Guan D, Barua A (2007) Changing lifestyles and consumption patterns in developing countries: A scenario analysis for China and India. Futures 39 (9): 1084-1096. https://core.ac.uk/download/pdf/51098.pdf Israel K (2015) Reconsidering the long-run relationship between inflation and unemployment http://www2.gcc.edu/dept/econ/ assc/Papers 2015/ASSC 2015 - Israel, Karl-Friedrich.pdf Ivanov V, Kilian L (2005) A practitioner’s guide to lag order selection for VAR impulse response analysis. Studies in Non- linear Dynamics & Econometrics 9 (1): 1-36.
  • 80. Katria S, Bhutto NA, Butt F, Domki AA, Khawaja HA, Khalid J (2011) Tradeoff between inflation and unemployment. In: Proceedings of 2nd International Conference on Business Management, 1-18 https://www.umt.edu.pk/icobm2012/ pdf/2C-90P.pdf Kebschull D (1987) The role of the agricultural sector in the South by. Intereconomics, 125-126. https://doi.org/10.1007/ BF02932233 Keynes JM (1936) The general theory of employment, interest, and money. MacMillan and Cambridge University Press. Kogid M, Asid R, Mulok D, Lily J, Loganathan N (2011) Inf- lation-unemployment trade-off relationship in Malaysia. Asian Journal of Business and Management Sciences 1 (1): 100-108 http://medcontent.metapress.com/index/A65RM- 03P4874243N.pdf%5Cnhttp://www.ajbms.org/articlepdf/ ajbms_2011_1124.pdf Lütkepohl H (2006) New introduction to multiple time series analysis. New York: Springer-Verlag. Mahmood Y, Bokhari R, Aslam M (2013) Trade-off between Inflation, Interest and unemployment rate of Pakistan: A coin- tegration analysis. Pakistan Journal of Commerce and Social Sciences 7 (3): 482-492 http://www.jespk.net/publications/140.pdf Mankiw NG, Euston Q, Wilson P (2013) Principles of economics: an Asian edition (2nd ed) Singapore: Cengage Learning Asia. Okafor IG, Chijindu EH, Ugochukwu US (2016) Responsiveness of unemployment to inflation: empirical evidence from Ni- geria. International Journal of Scientific Research in Science
  • 81. and Technology 2 (4): 173-179 https://www.researchgate. net/publication/311349523_Responsiveness_of_Unemploy- ment_to_Inflation_Empirical_Evidence_from_Nigeria Pallis D (2006) The trade-off between inflation and unemploy- ment in the New European Union Member-States. Interna- tional Research Journal of Finance and Economics (1): 80-88. Phllips AW (1958) The relation between unemployment and the rate of change of money wage rates in the United Kingdom. Economica 25 (100): 283-299. Business: Theory and Practice, 2019, 20: 1–10 9 Rosadi D (2012) Ekonometrika dan Analisis Runtun Waktu Terapan Dengan Eviews. Yogyakarta: ANDI. Sa’idu BM, Muhammad AA (2015) Do Unemployment and inflation substantially affect economic growth? Journal of Economics and Development Studies 3 (2): 132-139 https:// doi.org/10.15640/jeds.v3n2a13 Sasongko G, Huruta AD (2018) Monetary policy and the causality between inflation and money supply in Indonesia. Business: Theory and Practice 19: 80-87. https://doi.org/10.3846/ btp.2018.09 Ştefan C, Bratu A (2016) The inflation-unemployment tradeoff in a macroeconometric model. British Journal of Economics, Finance and Management Sciences 12 (1): 22-31 http://www. ajournal.co.uk/EFpdfs/EFvolume12(1)/EFVol.12 (1) Article 3.pdf
  • 82. Thayaparan A (2014) Impact of inflation on economic growth in Sri Lanka: a study of time series analysis. Global Jour- nal of Management and Business Research: B Economics and Commerce 13 (5): 45-54. https://doi.org/10.11648/j. jwer.20160501.11 Touny MA (2013) Investigate the long-run trade-off betwe- en inflation and unemployment in Egypt. International Journal of Economics and Finance 5 (7): 115-125. https:// doi.org/10.5539/ijef.v5n7p115 Ul-Haq I, Khan S, Khan A, Ahmed E (2012) Phillips curve or locus critique: time series evidence from Pakistan. Journal of Economics and Behavioral Studies 4 (4): 190-193 https://www. researchgate.net/publication/301551781_Revisiting_the_Phil- lips_Curve_and_the_Lucas_Critique Umaru A, Zubairu AA (2012) An empirical analysis of the re- lationship between unemployment and inflation in Nigeria from 1977–2009. Economics and Finance Review 1 (12): 42-61. https://doi.org/10.1111/1467-8268.00061 Yelwa M, David OOK, Omoniyi AE (2015) Analysis of the re- lationship between inflation, unemployment and economic growth in Nigeria: 1987–2012. Applied Economics and Finance 2 (3): 102-109. https://doi.org/10.11114/aef.v2i3.943 Zaman K, Khan MM, Ahmad M, Ikram W (2011) Inflation, unemployment and the NAIRU in Pakistan (1975–2009). International Journal of Economics and Finance 3 (1): 245- 254. https://doi.org/10.1016/S2212-5671(12)00015-9 10 G. Sasongko, A. D. Huruta. The causality between inflation and unemployment: the Indonesian evidence