SlideShare a Scribd company logo
Page 1 of 13
On HJM Model and Its Extension to Single-Currency-Multiple-
Curves Modelling
(Version 1 – 2017 Part I)
Chong Seng Choi
ARTICLE INFO ABSTRACT
Keywords:
Change-of-measure
Convexity adjustment
Credit crisis
Cross-currency derivatives
Discount curve
FRAs
Forward curve
Libor rates
No-arbitrage
OIS rates
Yield curve
Classical interest-rate models are developed to incorporate no-arbitrage conditions,
which allow one to hedge interest rate derivatives in terms of zero-coupon bonds.
As a result, forward rates with different tenors are related to each other by sharp
constraints, and these constraints between rates allowed the construction of a well-
defined forward curve. However, after the credit crunch in August 2007, the Libor
and OIS (risk-free) rates are separated by large basis spreads, which are no longer
considered negligible. As a result, FRA rates can no longer be replicated by the spot
Libor rates, and rates differing only for their payment frequency have started to
show large inconsistencies. The present market situation has thus necessitated the
development of single-currency-multiple-curves framework to take into account the
divergences between rates. This paper aims at reviewing the classical HJM model
and its extension to single-currency-multiple-curves valuation following a foreign-
currency analogy. The valuation of FRA is examined and a convexity adjustment
factor typical to the pricing of cross-currency derivatives is derived as a result.
1. Introduction
Classical interest-rate models are developed to incorporate
no-arbitrage conditions, which allow one to hedge interest
rate derivatives in terms of zero-coupon bonds. As a result,
forward rates with different tenors are related to each other
by sharp constraints, and these constraints between rates
allowed the construction of a well-defined forward curve.
However, after the credit crunch in August 2007, a
number of anomalies have emerged in that the market
quotes of forward rates and zero-coupon bonds started to
violate the no-arbitrage conditions embedded in these
classical models. In the pre-crisis environment, the Libor
and OIS (risk-free) rates were chasing each other closely,
the spreads between swap rates with the same maturity but
different payment lengths were negligible, and the market
quotes of FRA had the precise relationship with the spot
Libor rates that classical models predict. Therefore, the
pre-crisis standard market practice was to construct only
one unique yield curve and then compute on the same
curve the discount and forward rates.
Yet, in the post-crisis environment, the Libor and OIS
rates are separated by large basis spreads, which are no
longer considered negligible. As a result, FRA rates can
no longer be replicated by the spot Libor rates, and rates
differing only for their payment frequency have started to
show large inconsistencies. For example, as noted by
Mercurio (2009), a swap rate with semi-annual payments
1
For the rationale of choosing the HJM model, see
Cuchiero, Fontana and Gnoatto (2014), and Theis (2017).
based on the 6-month LIBOR can be different (and higher)
than the same-maturity swap rate but with quarterly
payments based on the 3-month LIBOR.
These divergences between rates thus suggest that
construction of a unique single yield curve for both
discounting and forwarding is possible only in the absence
of liquidity and counterparty risks. Indeed, the present
market situation has necessitated the development of
single-currency-multiple-curves framework to value
interest rate derivatives in that a unique curve is built for
discounting and separate curves corresponding to different
rate tenors, i.e. 1M, 3M,6M and 12M, are constructed for
forwarding.
This paper aims at reviewing the classical HJM1
model
and its extension to single-currency-multiple-curves
valuation following the foreign-currency analogy put
forward by Bianchetti (2009), Cuchiero, Fontana and
Gnoatto (2014), and Theis (2017). The valuation of FRA
is examined and a convexity adjustment typical to the
pricing of cross-currency derivatives is derived as a result.
Section 2 gives the mathematical notations used. Section
3 presents the derivations of the HJM model and Section
4 derives the dynamics of the forwarding curve under risk-
neutral and forward probability measures. Section 5
briefly discusses the implementation and estimation
procedure. Section 6 concludes.
 On HJM Model and Its Extension to Single-Currency-Multiple-Curves Modelling
Page 2 of 13
2. Mathematical Notation
Assuming a continuous-time trading economy with
trading interval [0, 𝑇∗
] for a fixed horizon 𝑇∗
> 0. The
uncertainty of the economy is defined on a probability
space (Ω, 𝔽, ℙ) with filtration 𝔽, which is assumed to be
the right-continuous and ℙ -completed version of the
filtration generated by the underlying d-dimensional
standard Brownian motion 𝑊.
Further, assuming there exists a continuum of non-
defaultable zero-coupon bonds with maturities 𝑇 ∈
[0, 𝑇∗], and let 𝐵(𝑡, 𝑇) denotes the price of the zero-
coupon bond at time 𝑡 ≤ 𝑇, 𝑡 ∈ [0, 𝑇], maturing at time
𝑇 ≤ 𝑇∗
. The bond price 𝐵(𝑡, 𝑇) is a strictly positive real-
valued adopted process with 𝐵(𝑇, 𝑇) = 1, and its partial
derivative with respect to maturity T, 𝜕 𝑇 ln 𝐵(𝑡, 𝑇), exits
for all 𝑇 ∈ [0, 𝑇∗
] . Lastly, let 𝔼ℙ(∙) denotes the
expectation under the probability measure ℙ.
Let 𝐹(𝑡, 𝑇, 𝑇 + 𝛿) be the forward rates at time 𝑡 < 𝑇 for
risk-free borrowing and lending at time 𝑇 maturing at time
𝑇 + 𝛿. Moreover, let 𝑓(𝑡, 𝑇) stands for the forward rate at
time 𝑡 ≤ 𝑇 for instantaneous risk-free borrowing and
lending at time 𝑇 ≤ 𝑇∗
. By taking the limit on 𝛿
𝑓(𝑡, 𝑇) = lim
𝛿→0
𝐹(𝑡, 𝑇, 𝑇 + 𝛿)
= − lim
𝛿→0
1
𝐵(𝑡, 𝑇 + 𝛿)
𝐵(𝑡, 𝑇 + 𝛿) − 𝐵(𝑡, 𝑇)
𝛿
= −
1
𝐵(𝑡, 𝑇)
𝜕𝐵(𝑡, 𝑇)
𝜕𝑇
= −
𝜕 ln 𝐵(𝑡, 𝑇)
𝜕𝑇
(Brigo and Mercurio, 2006:p.12)
The instantaneous forward rate 𝑓(𝑡, 𝑇) is thus given by
𝑓(𝑡, 𝑇) = − 𝜕 𝑇 ln 𝐵(𝑡, 𝑇) ∀ 𝑡 ∈ [0, 𝑇]
(1)
Integrating both sides and solving the above differential
equation yields the following formula for zero bonds
𝐵(𝑡, 𝑇) = exp (− ∫ 𝑓(𝑡, 𝑠)𝑑𝑠
𝑇
𝑡
) ∀ 𝑡 ∈ [0, 𝑇]
(2)
3. The Classical HJM Model
Previous interest rate models such as those of Vasicek
(1977), Cox, Ingersoll, and Ross (1985), and Hull and
White (1990) typically involved modelling directly the
dynamics of the short rate 𝑟 since all fundamental
quantities such as rates and bonds are readily defined,
which facilitated a convenient specification. Further, the
success of these models were mainly attributed to their
analytical tractability and the availability of explicit
2
The Vasicek and the Hull-White models are two
examples that produce negative rates with positive
probability due to their assumptions of a Gaussian
distribution.
3
The bond prices of most short-rate models such as those
of Vasicek (1977), Dothan (1978), Cox, Ingersoll, and
formulas for bonds and bond options (Brigo and Mercurio,
2006). Despite their advantages, these models generally
come with a major drawback in that the initial term
structure is endogenous rather than exogenous, meaning
that the initial term structure is an output of these models.
These endogenous term-structure models thus require
users to run optimization to find the set of model
parameters that fits as close as possible the initial curve to
the market curve (Brigo and Mercurio, 2006). However,
due to the small number of parameters in these short-rate
models, it is often difficult to calibrate an accurate initial
curve, and in some cases2
produce negative rates 𝑟𝑡 < 0.
In-light of the major disadvantage of most short-rate
models, one is thus in-need for a model that takes the
initial term structure as exogenously given. The first such
alternative was proposed by Ho and Lee (1986), who
modelled the behaviour of the entire yield curve in a
discrete setting instead of modelling the short-rate, which
represented only a single point on this curve (Musiela and
Rutkowski, 1997). Their intuition was then extended by
Heath, Jarrow and Mortion (HJM) (1992) in a continuous
time setting in that the instantaneous forward rates were
chosen to be the fundamental quantities to model. The
advantages of the HJM model lie not only in the
exogenous term-structure but also in the fact that nearly all
exogenous term-structure interest rate model can be
derived within this general framework (Brigo and
Mercurio, 2006). In particular, the HJM model links
together the dynamics of forward rates and zero-coupon
bond prices and assumes that the zero bonds evolve as a
continuous stochastic process3
. Therefore, the HJM model
is also a natural choice for single-currency-multiple-
curves modelling.
3.1 HJM Forward-Rate Dynamics
Heath, Jarrow and Morton (1992) assumes that for every
fixed 𝑇 ≤ 𝑇∗
, the dynamics of the instantaneous forward
rate satisfies the following stochastic process
𝑓(𝑡, 𝑇) = 𝑓(0, 𝑇) + ∫ 𝛼(𝑠, 𝑇)𝑑𝑠 + ∫ 𝜎(𝑠, 𝑇)𝑑𝑊(𝑠)
𝑡
0
𝑡
0
(3)
for all 𝑡 ∈ [0, 𝑇], where 𝑓(0, 𝑇) = 𝑓 𝑀(0, 𝑇): [0, 𝑇∗] is
the market instantaneous forward curve at time 𝑡 = 0, i.e.
initial term structure. 𝑓(0,∙): [0, 𝑇∗
] → ℝ is a Borel-
measurable function and 𝛼 ∶ 𝐶 × Ω → ℝ and 𝜎 ∶ 𝐶 ×
Ω → ℝ 𝑑
are some functions such that 𝐶 = {(𝑠, 𝑡)|0 ≤ 𝑠 ≤
𝑡 ≤ 𝑇∗}.
Moreover, for any maturity T, 𝛼(∙, 𝑇) is an adopted
process, and 𝜎(∙, 𝑇) = (𝜎1(∙, 𝑇), … , 𝜎 𝑑(∙, 𝑇)) is a vector of
adopted processes such that
Ross (1985), and Hull and White (1990) are derived by
solving the time-t conditional expectation 𝐵(𝑡, 𝑇) =
𝔼 𝑡 {𝑒𝑥𝑝 (− ∫ 𝑟(𝑢)𝑑𝑢
𝑇
𝑡
)} and thus are no stochastic (see
Brigo and Mercurio, 2006).
 On HJM Model and Its Extension to Single-Currency-Multiple-Curves Modelling
Page 3 of 13
∫ |𝛼(𝑠, 𝑇)|𝑑𝑠 + ∫ ‖𝜎(𝑠, 𝑇)‖2
𝑑𝑠 < ∞,
𝑇
𝑡
ℙ
𝑇
𝑡
− 𝑎. 𝑠
(Musiela and Rutkowski, 1997)
In this setup, the D-dimensional Brownian motion
determines the stochastic dynamics of the entire forward
rate term structure starting from the fixed initial term
structure 𝑓 𝑀(0, 𝑇).
3.2 HJM Bond Price Dynamics
For every fixed 𝑇 ≤ 𝑇∗
, assuming the dynamics of the
bond price 𝐵(𝑡, 𝑇) are determined by the following
expression
𝜕𝐵(𝑡, 𝑇) = 𝐵(𝑡, 𝑇)(𝑎(𝑡, 𝑇)𝑑𝑡 + 𝑏(𝑡, 𝑇)𝑑𝑊(𝑡))
(5)
With the above HJM assumptions and equations (2) and
(3), the discount bond process can be solved for in the
following steps
𝐵(𝑡, 𝑇) = exp (− ∫ 𝑓(𝑡, 𝑠)𝑑𝑠
𝑇
𝑡
)
= exp
(
−
(
∫ 𝑓(0, 𝑢)𝑑𝑢 + ∫ ∫ 𝛼(𝑠, 𝑢)𝑑𝑠𝑑𝑢
𝑡
0
𝑇
𝑡
𝑇
𝑡
+ ∫ ∫ 𝜎(𝑠, 𝑢)𝑑𝑊(𝑠)𝑑𝑢
𝑡
0
𝑇
𝑡 ))
By the Fubini’s standard and stochastic theorems,
∫ ∫ 𝛼(𝑠, 𝑢)𝑑𝑠𝑑𝑢
𝑡
0
𝑇
0
= ∫ ∫ 𝛼(𝑠, 𝑢)𝑑𝑢𝑑𝑠
𝑇
0
𝑡
0
= ∫ ∫ 𝛼(𝑠, 𝑢)𝑑𝑢𝑑𝑠 + ∫ ∫ 𝛼(𝑠, 𝑢)𝑑𝑢𝑑𝑠
𝑡
𝑠
𝑡
0
𝑇
𝑠
𝑡
0
= ∫ ∫ 𝛼(𝑢, 𝑠)𝑑𝑠𝑑𝑢 + ∫ ∫ 𝛼(𝑠, 𝑢)𝑑𝑠𝑑𝑢
𝑢
0
𝑡
0
𝑇
𝑢
𝑡
0
and the same holds for ∬ 𝜎(𝑠, 𝑢)𝑑𝑊𝑠 𝑑𝑢,
∫ ∫ 𝜎(𝑠, 𝑢)𝑑𝑊𝑠 𝑑𝑢
𝑡
0
𝑇
0
= ∫ ∫ 𝜎(𝑠, 𝑢)𝑑𝑢𝑑𝑊(𝑠)
𝑇
0
𝑡
0
= ∫ ∫ 𝜎(𝑠, 𝑢)𝑑𝑢𝑑𝑊𝑠 + ∫ ∫ 𝜎(𝑠, 𝑢)𝑑𝑢𝑑𝑊(𝑠)
𝑡
𝑠
𝑡
0
𝑇
𝑠
𝑡
0
= ∫ ∫ 𝜎(𝑢, 𝑠)𝑑𝑠𝑑𝑊𝑢 + ∫ ∫ 𝜎(𝑠, 𝑢)𝑑𝑢𝑑𝑊(𝑠)
𝑢
0
𝑡
0
𝑇
𝑢
𝑡
0
we thus have 𝐵(𝑡, 𝑇) = exp
(
− ∫ 𝑓(0, 𝑢)𝑑𝑢 − ∫ ∫ 𝛼(𝑢, 𝑠)𝑑𝑠𝑑𝑢
𝑇
𝑢
𝑡
0
𝑇
0
– ∫ ∫ 𝜎(𝑢, 𝑠)𝑑𝑠𝑑𝑊(𝑢)
𝑇
𝑢
𝑡
0
+
∫ (𝑓(0, 𝑢) + ∫ 𝛼(𝑠, 𝑢)𝑑𝑠
𝑢
0
+ ∫ 𝜎(𝑠, 𝑢)𝑑𝑊(𝑠)
𝑢
0
)
⏟
𝑑𝑢
𝑡
0
𝑓(𝑢, 𝑢) )
(6)
Moreover, the short rate 𝑟𝑢 at time 𝑢 can be derived
using the forward rate equation and taking the limit on 𝛿
over the time interval [𝑢, 𝑢 + 𝛿]
𝑟𝑢 = 𝑓(𝑢, 𝑢) = lim
𝛿→0
[𝛿−1
(
1 − 𝐵(𝑢, 𝑢 + 𝛿)
𝐵(𝑢, 𝑢 + 𝛿)
)]
= 𝑓(0, 𝑢) + ∫ 𝛼(𝑠, 𝑢)𝑑𝑠
𝑢
0
+ ∫ 𝜎(𝑠, 𝑢)𝑑𝑊(𝑠)
𝑢
0
(7)
(Heath, Jarrow and Morton, 1992)
Writing equation (6) in the form of an 𝐼𝑡𝑜̃ process, we
have 𝐵(𝑡, 𝑇) =
𝐵(0, 𝑇)
𝑒𝑥𝑝 (∫ 𝑟𝑢 𝑑𝑢 − ∫ ⋀(𝑢, 𝑇)𝑑𝑢 + ∫ Σ(𝑢, 𝑇)𝑑𝑊(𝑢)
𝑡
0
𝑡
0
𝑡
0
)
(8)
where
𝐵(0, 𝑇) = exp (− ∫ 𝑓(0, 𝑢)𝑑𝑢
𝑇
0
)
⋀(𝑢, 𝑇) = ∫ 𝛼(𝑡, 𝑠)𝑑𝑠,
𝑇
𝑡
Σ(𝑢, 𝑇) = ∫ 𝜎(𝑡, 𝑠)𝑑𝑠
𝑇
𝑡
The coefficients in equation (5) can be derived using
equation (8) and the 𝐼𝑡𝑜̃ formula to solve for 𝐵(𝑡, 𝑇) =
ln(𝐵(𝑡, 𝑇)).
In differential form, equation (8) equals
𝜕𝐵(𝑡, 𝑇) = 𝐵(𝑡, 𝑇)[(𝑟𝑡 − ⋀(𝑡, 𝑇)𝑑𝑡 + Σ(𝑡, 𝑇)𝑑𝑊(𝑡)]
and by the 𝐼𝑡𝑜̃ formula,
𝜕𝐵(𝑡, 𝑇)
𝐵(𝑡, 𝑇)
= 𝜕𝐵(𝑡, 𝑇) +
1
2
[𝜕𝐵(𝑡, 𝑇)]2
= (𝑟𝑡 − ⋀(𝑡, 𝑇) +
1
2
|Σ(𝑡, 𝑇)|2
) 𝑑𝑡 − Σ(𝑡, 𝑇)𝑑𝑊(𝑡)
(9)
Thus, we have
𝑎(𝑡, 𝑇) = 𝑟𝑡 − ⋀(𝑡, 𝑇) +
1
2
|Σ(𝑡, 𝑇)|2
and,
𝑏(𝑡, 𝑇) = − Σ(𝑡, 𝑇)
3.3 No-Arbitrage Condition
In the HJM setting, a continuum of bonds with different
maturities, 0 < 𝑇1
< 𝑇2
< ⋯ < 𝑇 𝑘
≤ 𝑇∗
, is available for
trade, therefore, one must ensure that there is no
opportunity for arbitrage by trading bonds with different
maturities.
From The First Fundamental Theorem of Asset Pricing,
the bond price process 𝐵(𝑡, 𝑇), 𝑡 ≤ 𝑇 ≤ 𝑇∗
, is arbitrage
 On HJM Model and Its Extension to Single-Currency-Multiple-Curves Modelling
Page 4 of 13
free if and only if there exits a probability measure ℙ̃ on
(Ω, 𝔽 𝑇∗̃) that is equivalent to ℙ such that for any maturity
𝑇 ∈ [0, 𝑇∗], the discounted bond price
𝐵(𝑡,𝑇)
𝐵𝑡
is a
martingale under ℙ̃.
Let us first introduce the saving account 𝐵𝑡, which is
also an adapted process defined on a filtered probability
space (Ω, 𝔽, ℙ). 𝐵𝑡 is the amount of cash accumulated up
to time 𝑡 by rolling over a risk-free bond and starting with
one unit of cash at time 0. Thus, the process for 𝐵𝑡 is given
by
𝐵𝑡 = exp (∫ 𝑓(𝑢, 𝑢)𝑑𝑢
𝑡
0
) ∀ 𝑡 ∈ [0, 𝑇∗
]
(10)
where
𝐵0 = 1, 0 < 𝐵𝑡 < +∞
By the 𝐼𝑡𝑜̃ quotient rule
𝜕(𝐵(𝑡, 𝑇)/𝐵𝑡)
𝐵(𝑡, 𝑇)/𝐵𝑡
=
𝜕𝐵(𝑡, 𝑇)
𝐵(𝑡, 𝑇)
−
𝜕𝐵𝑡
𝐵𝑡
+
𝜕[𝐵𝑡, 𝐵𝑡]
𝐵𝑡
2 −
𝜕[𝐵(𝑡, 𝑇), 𝐵𝑡]
𝐵(𝑡, 𝑇)𝐵𝑡
= (𝑟𝑡 − ⋀(𝑡, 𝑇) +
1
2
|Σ(𝑡, 𝑇)|2
) 𝑑𝑡 − Σ(𝑡, 𝑇)𝑑𝑊(𝑡) − 𝑟𝑡 𝑑𝑡
= (−⋀(𝑡, 𝑇) +
1
2
|Σ(𝑡, 𝑇)|2
) 𝑑𝑡 − Σ(𝑡, 𝑇)𝑑𝑊(𝑡)
(11)
where
𝜕𝐵𝑡 = 𝐵𝑡 𝑟𝑡 𝑑𝑡
(12)
From the above conditions, there must exist a
probability measure measure ℙ̃ on (Ω, 𝔽 𝑇∗̃ ) equivalent to
ℙ in order to ensure that there is no opportunity for
arbitrage. In a financial interpretation, the underlying
probability measure ℙ represents actual probability,
which is a subjective assessment of the future evolution of
the discounted bond price and therefore is not a martingale
under ℙ. On the other hand, the probability measure ℙ̃
reflects risk-neutral probability, which renders the
discounted bond price a martingale under ℙ̃ with zero drift.
Defining 𝑍(𝑡, 𝑇) =
𝐵(𝑡,𝑇)
𝐵𝑡
and rearranging the terms in
(11), we have
𝜕𝑍(𝑡, 𝑇)
𝑍(𝑡, 𝑇)
= − Σ(𝑡, 𝑇)[𝜃𝑡 𝑑𝑡 + 𝑑𝑊(𝑡)]
(13)
where
𝜃𝑡 =
−⋀(𝑡, 𝑇) +
1
2
|Σ(𝑡, 𝑇)|2
− Σ(𝑡, 𝑇)
(14)
is the market price of risk under the probability measure
ℙ. We can then proceed to define a new probability
measure ℙ̃ equivalent to ℙ on (Ω, 𝔽 𝑇∗̃ ) using the 𝑅𝑎𝑑𝑜𝑛
-𝑁𝑖𝑘𝑜𝑑𝑦́ 𝑚 𝑑𝑒𝑟𝑖𝑣𝑎𝑡𝑖𝑣𝑒
𝜕ℙ̃
𝜕ℙ
= ℇ 𝑇∗ (∫ 𝜃𝑡
∙
0
𝑑𝑊𝑡) ℙ − 𝑎. 𝑠.
for some predictable ℝ 𝑑
-valued process adopted to the
filtration 𝔽 𝑊
. The notation ℇ(∙) is the
𝐷𝑜𝑙𝑒́ 𝑎 𝑛𝑠 𝑒𝑥𝑝𝑜𝑛𝑒𝑛𝑡𝑖𝑎𝑙, which gives
ℇ 𝑇∗ (∫ 𝜃𝑡
∙
0
𝑑𝑊𝑡) = 𝑒𝑥𝑝 (∫ 𝜃 𝑢
𝑡
0
𝑑𝑊(𝑢) −
1
2
∫ |𝜃 𝑢|2
𝑡
0
𝑑𝑊(𝑢))
In view of Girsanov’s Theorem, the process
𝑊̃ (𝑡) = 𝑊(𝑡) + ∫ 𝜃 𝑢
𝑡
0
𝑑𝑢 ∀ 𝑡 ∈ [0, 𝑇∗
]
(15)
follows a d-dimensional Brownian motion under ℙ̃. Thus
we can change the probability measure of 𝑍(𝑡, 𝑇) from ℙ
to ℙ̃
𝜕𝑍(𝑡, 𝑇)
𝑍(𝑡, 𝑇)
= − Σ(𝑡, 𝑇)[𝜃𝑡 𝑑𝑡 + (𝑑𝑊̃ (𝑡) − 𝜃𝑡 𝑑𝑡)]
= − Σ(𝑡, 𝑇) 𝑑𝑊̃ (𝑡)
(16)
which is a martingale under ℙ̃.
Since equation (11) and (13) are equivalent, we can then
derive 𝛼(𝑡, 𝑇) in the forward process (3), under the
measure ℙ, by solving the following equation
(−⋀(𝑡, 𝑇) +
1
2
|Σ(𝑡, 𝑇)|2
) 𝑑𝑡 − Σ(𝑡, 𝑇)𝑑𝑊(𝑡)
= − Σ(𝑡, 𝑇)[𝜃𝑡 𝑑𝑡 + 𝑑𝑊(𝑡)]
−⋀(𝑡, 𝑇) +
1
2
|Σ(𝑡, 𝑇)|2
= − Σ(𝑡, 𝑇)𝜃𝑡
(17)
and by differentiating the equation with respect to T
𝜕 𝑇 [−⋀(𝑡, 𝑇) +
1
2
|Σ(𝑡, 𝑇)|2
] = 𝜕 𝑇[− Σ(𝑡, 𝑇)𝜃𝑡]
−𝛼(𝑡, 𝑇) + Σ(𝑡, 𝑇)𝜎(𝑡, 𝑇) = 𝜎(𝑡, 𝑇)𝜃𝑡
𝛼(𝑡, 𝑇) = 𝜎(𝑡, 𝑇)[Σ(𝑡, 𝑇) + 𝜃𝑡]
(18)
Thus, under the actual measure ℙ, we have
𝜕𝑓(𝑡, 𝑇)
𝑓(𝑡, 𝑇)
= (𝜎(𝑡, 𝑇)Σ(𝑡, 𝑇) + 𝜎(𝑡, 𝑇)𝜃𝑡)𝑑𝑡 + 𝜎(𝑡, 𝑇)𝑑𝑊(𝑡)
(19)
𝜕𝐵(𝑡, 𝑇)
𝐵(𝑡, 𝑇)
= (𝑟𝑡 − Σ(𝑡, 𝑇)𝜃𝑡)𝑑𝑡 − Σ(𝑡, 𝑇)𝑑𝑊(𝑡)
(20)
 On HJM Model and Its Extension to Single-Currency-Multiple-Curves Modelling
Page 5 of 13
𝜕𝑍(𝑡, 𝑇)
𝑍(𝑡, 𝑇)
= − Σ(𝑡, 𝑇)[𝜃𝑡 𝑑𝑡 + 𝑑𝑊(𝑡)]
(21)
If a term-structure model satisfies the HJM no-arbitrage
conditions then under the risk-neutral probability measure
ℙ̃ and by Girsanov’s Theorem in (15), we have
𝜕𝑓(𝑡, 𝑇)
𝑓(𝑡, 𝑇)
= 𝜎(𝑡, 𝑇)Σ(𝑡, 𝑇)𝑑𝑡 + 𝜎(𝑡, 𝑇)𝑑𝑊̃ (𝑡)
(22)
and the zero-coupon bond prices
𝜕𝐵(𝑡, 𝑇)
𝐵(𝑡, 𝑇)
= 𝑟𝑡 𝑑𝑡 − Σ(𝑡, 𝑇)𝑑𝑊̃ (𝑡)
(23)
and the discounted bond prices
𝜕𝑍(𝑡, 𝑇)
𝑍(𝑡, 𝑇)
= − Σ(𝑡, 𝑇) 𝑑𝑊̃ (𝑡)
(24)
Equations (19) - (24) are intuitive in that, under the risk-
neutral expectation, the bond price satisfies
𝐵(𝑡, 𝑇) = 𝐵𝑡 𝔼 𝑡
ℙ̃
(𝐵 𝑇
−1
|ℱ𝑡)
= 𝔼 𝑡
ℙ̃
(𝑒𝑥𝑝 (− ∫ 𝑓(𝑢, 𝑢)𝑑𝑢
𝑇
𝑡
)| ℱ𝑡)
Consequently, given any non-negative forward rate
process 𝑓 defined on a probability space (Ω, 𝔽, ℙ) and a
probability measure ℙ̃ on (Ω, 𝔽 𝑇∗̃) equivalent to ℙ, the
market price of risk 𝜃 must vanish under the risk-neutral
measure ℙ̃.
The HJM no-arbitrage conditions are best summarized
as follow
I. For any collection of maturities 0 < 𝑇1
< 𝑇2
<
⋯ < 𝑇 𝑘
≤ 𝑇∗
, there exit market prices of risk
𝜃 𝑖(∙ ; 𝒯) such that
−⋀𝑖(∙, 𝒯) +
1
2
|Σ 𝑖(∙, 𝒯)|
2
+ Σ 𝑖(∙, 𝒯)𝜃 𝑖(∙ ; 𝒯) = 0
which satisfies
∫ |𝜃 𝑖(𝑢 ; 𝒯)|
2
𝑇 𝑖
0
𝑑𝑢 < +∞ 𝑓𝑜𝑟 𝑖 = 1, … , 𝑘
and
𝔼ℙ
(ℇ 𝑇∗ (∫ 𝜃 𝑖(𝑢 ; 𝒯)
∙
0
𝑑𝑊 𝑖
(𝑢))) = 1
and
4
In a FRA contact, a fixed payment based on the strike K,
set at time 𝑡, is exchanged against a floating payment at
𝔼ℙ
(ℇ 𝑇∗ (∫ (Σ 𝑖(𝑢, 𝒯) + 𝜃 𝑖(𝑢 ; 𝒯))
∙
0
𝑑𝑊 𝑖
(𝑢))) = 1
for 𝒯 ∈ [𝑇1
, … , 𝑇 𝑘
] and 𝑖 = 1, … , 𝑘
II. There exits a probability measure ℙ̃ equivalent to ℙ
such that for any collection of maturities 0 < 𝑇1
<
𝑇2
< ⋯ < 𝑇 𝑘
≤ 𝑇∗
the discounted bond prices
𝑍(∙, 𝒯) are martingales under ℙ̃ with respect to
𝑓(∙, 𝒯).
III. The martingale measures in (II) are unique across
all bonds of all maturities 0 < 𝑇1
< 𝑇2
< ⋯ <
𝑇 𝑘
≤ 𝑇∗
where
 ℙ̃ is defined as ℙ̃ 𝑇1,…,𝑇 𝑘 for any maturity 0 <
𝑇1
< ⋯ < 𝑇 𝑘
≤ 𝑇∗
and ℙ̃ 𝑇 𝑖 is the unique
equivalent probability measure such that
𝑍(𝑡, 𝑇) is a martingale for all 𝑇 ∈ [0, 𝑇∗
] and
𝑡 ∈ [0, 𝑇 𝑖
]
 𝛼(𝑡, 𝑇) = ∑ 𝜎 𝑖(𝑡, 𝑇) [∫ 𝜎 𝑖(𝑡, 𝑢)𝑑𝑢
𝑇
𝑡
+ 𝜃 𝑖(∙𝑘
𝑖=1
; 𝒯)] for all 𝑇 ∈ [0, 𝑇∗
], 𝑡 ∈ [0, 𝑇] and for
any 𝒯 ∈ (0, 𝑇∗
],
Arbitrage-free bond pricing and term structure
movements (Heath, Jarrow and Merton, 1992:p. 83-87)
4. Post Liquidity Crisis
The direct result of the no-arbitrage conditions embedded
in HJM model and in other interest rate models is that they
link together the forward rates and zero-coupon bonds, and
thus allow one to price and hedge interest rate derivatives
on any single currency. In fixed income markets, the
underlying quantities of majority of interest-rate sensitive
products are the Libor rates 𝐿(𝑡, 𝑇, 𝑇 + 𝛿), where 𝛿 > 0
corresponds to the underlying rate tenors 1D, 1M, 3M, 6M,
and 12M. In the classical setting, the Libor rates are
associated with the forward rates 𝐹 under a forward
probability measure, namely
𝔼 𝑡
ℙ̃ 𝑇+𝛿
(𝐿(𝑇, 𝑇, 𝑇 + 𝛿)|ℱ𝑡) ≔ 𝐹(𝑡, 𝑇, 𝑇 + 𝛿)
(25)
and therefore the Libor rates can be replicated by buying
and selling zero bonds with maturities corresponding those
of the Libor rates, namely
𝐹(𝑡, 𝑇, 𝑇 + 𝛿) ≔ 𝛿−1
(
𝐵(𝑡, 𝑇)
𝐵(𝑡, 𝑇 + 𝛿)
− 1)
(26)
where 𝛿 is the year fraction between times 𝑇 and 𝑇 + 𝛿. In
this sense, the discounted bonds 𝐵(𝑡, 𝑇) and the forward
rates 𝐹(𝑡, 𝑇, 𝑇 + 𝛿) are computed using the spot Libor
quotes prevailing in the market at time 𝑡, 𝐿 𝑀
(𝑡, 𝑇). Taking
as example the pricing of FRA 4
(Forward Rate
maturity, 𝑇 + 𝛿, based on the spot Libor rate at time at
maturity 𝑇 for period [𝑇, 𝑇 + 𝛿].
 On HJM Model and Its Extension to Single-Currency-Multiple-Curves Modelling
Page 6 of 13
Agreement), the valuation of such contract, assuming a $1
notional, is given by
FRA (𝑡, 𝑇, 𝑇 + 𝛿, 𝐾) = 𝐵(𝑡, 𝑇 + 𝛿)𝛿(𝐾 − 𝐿(𝑡, 𝑇, 𝑇 + 𝛿))
(Brigo and Mercurio, 2006)
where 𝐾 is the strike that renders the contract fair at
initiation time 𝑡. Thus we have the time 𝑡 price of a FRA
equals to the strike 𝐾, giving
𝐾 = 𝔼 𝑡
ℙ̃ 𝑇+𝛿
(𝐿(𝑇, 𝑇, 𝑇 + 𝛿)|ℱ𝑡) = 𝛿−1
(
𝐵(𝑡, 𝑇)
𝐵(𝑡, 𝑇 + 𝛿)
− 1)
(27)
In this setting, Libor is not only the rate to which the
FRA is referenced but also the rate used to discount future
cash-flows. It is thus assumed that the risk in the interbank
lending market is negligible, and Libor rates can be
considered risk-free. As stressed by Bianchetti (2009), this
setting is known as single-currency-single-curve
approach in that a unique yield curve is constructed and
used to price and hedge interest rate derivatives on a given
currency.
Before the crisis in 2007, the OIS5
, commonly used as
the risk-free rate, and Libor rates were closely tracking
each other, and the market quotes of FRA rates had a
precise relationship with the spot Libor rates that the FRAs
are indexed to, i.e. equation (27). Yet, after the financial
crisis in 2007-2008 and the Eurozone sovereign debt crisis
in 2009-2012, the classical assumptions do not hold
anymore, with the basis spreads between the OIS and
Libor rates now larger than those in the past and are no
longer considered negligible. The main reasons behind
this phenomenon can be attributed to counterparty risk, the
risk of the counterparty defaulting on the contract
obligation, and liquidity risk, the risk of excessive funding
cost to finance the contract due to the lack of liquidity in
the market. Unfortunately, the increase in the basis spreads
does not create any arbitrage opportunities when
counterparty and liquidity risks are taken into account
(Mercurio, 2009). Therefore, the FRA rates can no longer
be replicated by the spot Libor rates, and the floating legs
differing only for the tenor 𝛿 are now represented by large
basis spreads Morini (2009). Indeed, with the counterparty
and liquidity risk in mind, Libor rates are not longer
considered risk-free and the OIS rates are now a more
appropriate candidate for discounting future cash-flows.
The market has thus evolved to a single-currency-
multiple-curves approach to take into account the different
dynamics represented by Libor rates with different tenors
and the discount rates that should be represented by a
unique separate discounting curve. From Ametrano and
Bianchetti (2013) Section 2.2, the corresponding approach
can be summarized as follows:
 Build a unique discounting curve using the OIS rates
5
According to Morini (2009), ‘an OIS, Overnight Index
Swap, is a fixed/floating interest rate swap with the
floating leg tied to a published index of a daily overnight
 Build multiple forwarding curves for the Libor rates
associated with difference tenors 𝛿
 Use the market quotes of multiple separated sets of
vanilla interest rate instruments with increasing
maturity to bootstrap the forwarding curves
 Compute on the forwarding curves the forward rates
 Compute on the discounting curve the discount rates
Post-crisis procedure for constructing multiple yield
curves (Ametrano and Bianchetti, 2013:p.7)
Returning to the FRA pricing equation, we know that
equation (27) does not hold anymore
𝔼 𝑡
ℙ̃ 𝑇+𝛿
(𝐿(𝑇, 𝑇, 𝑇 + 𝛿)|ℱ𝑡) ≠ 𝛿−1
(
𝐵(𝑡, 𝑇)
𝐵(𝑡, 𝑇 + 𝛿)
− 1)
because now 𝐿(𝑡, 𝑇, 𝑇 + 𝛿) > 𝐹(𝑡, 𝑇, 𝑇 + 𝛿). Adopting
the multi-curves approach and the framework noted above,
we have the floating leg of the FRA given by
𝑭𝑹𝑨 𝒇𝒍𝒐𝒂𝒕𝒊𝒏𝒈 (𝑡, 𝑇, 𝑇 + 𝛿)
= 𝛿𝐵 𝑑(𝑡, 𝑇 + 𝛿) [𝛿−1
(
𝐵 𝑓(𝑡, 𝑇)
𝐵 𝑓(𝑡, 𝑇 + 𝛿)
− 1)]
= 𝛿𝐵 𝑑(𝑡, 𝑇 + 𝛿)[𝐹𝑓(𝑡, 𝑇, 𝑇 + 𝛿)]
(28)
where 𝐵 𝑑(𝑡, ∙ ) is the discount factors computed from the
discounting curve and 𝐵 𝑓(𝑡, ∙ ) is the zero bond prices
computed from the forwarding curves. Using the
martingale property of forward rates, we therefore need to
compute equation (28) with the following expectation
𝔼 𝑡
ℙ̃
𝑑
𝑇+𝛿
(𝐿(𝑇, 𝑇, 𝑇 + 𝛿)|ℱ𝑡) = 𝔼 𝑡
ℙ̃
𝑑
𝑇+𝛿
(𝐹𝑓(𝑇, 𝑇, 𝑇 + 𝛿))
(29)
where 𝔼 𝑡
ℙ̃
𝑑
𝑇+𝛿
is the expectation at time 𝑡 under the
discounting - 𝑇 + 𝛿 - forward neutral probability measure
ℙ̃ 𝑑
𝑇+𝛿
.
4.1 Multi-Curves Modelling
The single currency multi-curves modelling framework
was first proposed by Henrard (2007) who describes a
market in which each forward rate seems to act as a
separate underlying asset. Subsequently, other authors
have proposed several ways to go beyond the deterministic
basis spread assumption. Martinez (2009) derives the drift
conditions on a HJM model in the presence of a stochastic
basis but focuses only on risk-neutral measure. Mercurio
and Xie (2012) and Cuchiero, Fontana and Gnoatto (2014)
model the Libor-OIS spread directly as a stochastic
process.
While Cuchiero, Fontana and Gnoatto (2014) generalize
the HJM model, Mercurio (2010) extends the Libor
reference rate. Since an overnight rate refers to lending for
an extremely short period of time, it is assumed to
incorporate negligible credit or liquidity risk.’ (p.10)
 On HJM Model and Its Extension to Single-Currency-Multiple-Curves Modelling
Page 7 of 13
Market Model to incorporate an additive stochastic basis.
Moreover, OpenGamma (2012b) extends the Gaussian
HJM model to a multi-curves framework with
deterministic spread. Moreni and Pallavicini (2010) use a
HJM-LMM hybrid model in which the discounting curve
is described by a HJM dynamic while the forwarding
curves are modelled through a Libor Market approach. In
particular, Bianchetti (2009) and Theis (2017) recognizes
an analogy between FX pricing and the pricing of interest
rate derivatives when discounting is decoupled by
indexing (Morini, 2009), leading to a convexity adjustment
in the pricing equation.
In light of the simplicity of the foreign-currency
analogy examined by Bianchetti (2009) and Theis (2017),
we shall follow their approach and apply it to the HJM
model. The resulting single-currency-double-curves
framework can be easily extended to a multi-curves setting.
4.2 Foreign-Currency Analogy
Let us first consider the rationale behind this modelling
choice. As in Bianchetti (2009), and Cuchiero, Fontana
and Gnoatto (2014), one can associate the risky Libor rate
with artificial risky bonds 𝐵 𝑓(𝑡, 𝑇) issued by a bank
representative of the Libor panel. In this case, the pricing
procedure is consistent with the classical risk-free setting,
namely, 1+ 𝛿𝐿(𝑇, 𝑇, 𝑇 + 𝛿) =
1
𝐵 𝑓(𝑇,𝑇,𝑇+𝛿)
. Moreover, if we
interpret the risk-free bonds as domestic assets while the
artificial bonds as foreign assets expressed in unit of
foreign currency, we can introduce a spot “exchange” rate
𝑆𝑡, which allows us to link together the risk-free and the
artificial risky bonds. Applying this foreign-currency
analogy, we can proceed to derive a forward “exchange”
rate 𝐹𝑆(𝑡, 𝑇, 𝑇 + 𝛿) over the period [𝑡, 𝑇] for settlement
date 𝑇 + 𝛿 under the standard no-arbitrage argument in
the foreign exchange markets. Naturally, the quantity
𝐹𝑆(𝑡, 𝑇, 𝑇 + 𝛿) can be interpreted as a multiplicative
forward interest rate spread between the risk-free and
risky bonds over the period [𝑇, 𝑇 + 𝛿]. As we shall see,
different interpretations of the quantity 𝐹𝑆(𝑡, 𝑇, 𝑇 + 𝛿)
would give different results for the single-currency-
double-curves framework. Nonetheless, in-light of the
above discussion, the foreign-currency analogy remains a
natural modelling choice.
Conversely, as in Theis (2017), we can consider 𝑆𝑡
6
the
price at time 𝑡 of a unit of currency borrowed on a rolling
basis at the risk-free rate and invested in the risky rate
starting from time 0. In this sense, the foreign-currency
analogy allows one to absorb the credit risk through the
exchange rate 𝑆𝑡 and therefore treating the artificial risky
bond process as continuous and continuously evolving
consistent with standard interest rate modelling practice.
Nevertheless, let us consider the framework of
Bianchetti (2009) and assume that there exit two different
interest markets 𝑀 𝑥 with 𝑥 = {𝑑, 𝑓} denoting
respectively the domestic (discounting) and foreign
(forwarding) market. Moreover, there are also two distinct
6
In Theis (2017), the quantity 𝑆𝑡 models the cumulative
credit risk of an investment in the risky bonds, and it is
saving accounts 𝐵𝑡
𝑥
, thus in the HJM setting we have the
following dynamics under the 𝑥 - risk-neutral measure
𝜕𝑓 𝑥(𝑡, 𝑇)
𝑓 𝑥(𝑡, 𝑇)
= 𝜎 𝑥(𝑡, 𝑇)Σ 𝑥(𝑡, 𝑇)𝑑𝑡 + 𝜎 𝑥(𝑡, 𝑇)𝑑𝑊̃𝑥(𝑡)
(30)
𝜕𝐵 𝑥(𝑡, 𝑇)
𝐵 𝑥(𝑡, 𝑇)
= 𝑟𝑡
𝑥
𝑑𝑡 − Σ 𝑥(𝑡, 𝑇)𝑑𝑊̃𝑥(𝑡)
(31)
𝜕𝐵𝑡
𝑥
𝐵𝑡
𝑥 = 𝑟𝑡
𝑥
𝑑𝑡
(32)
Moreover, a tradable asset in a foreign currency 𝑓 is
tradable in the domestic market through the exchange rate
𝑆. Thus, if 𝑋 𝑓
is the price process of the foreign asset,
𝑋𝑡
𝑓
𝑆𝑡 will be the price process of the foreign asset in
domestic currency. From Theis (2017), there must exist a
pre-visible process 𝜎𝑡
𝑠
such that the exchange rate process
can be postulated as follow
𝜕𝑆𝑡
𝑆𝑡
= (𝜇 𝑡 𝑑𝑡 + 𝜎𝑡
𝑠
𝑑𝑊̃ 𝑆(𝑡))
(33)
where the process 𝑆𝑡 is defined on a filtered probability
space (Ω, 𝔽, ℙ) with the filtration 𝔽 assumed to be the ℙ-
augmentation of the filtration generated by a d-
dimensional Brownian motion and ∫ |𝜎 𝑢
𝑠|2
𝑑𝑢 <
𝑡
0
∞.
Putting aside the foreign-currency analogy, the process
𝑆 can be viewed as a spot interest rate spread expressed
as a ratio between the short rates 𝑓 𝑑
(𝑡, 𝑡)/𝑓 𝑓
(𝑡, 𝑡). In
order to rule out arbitrage between investments in the
domestic (discounting) and foreign (forwarding) assets,
we shall refer to the no-arbitrage conditions in (I) and (II),
in particular
 There exits a probability measure measure ℙ̃
equivalent to ℙ on (Ω, 𝔽 𝑇∗̃ ) such that the the foreign
money account 𝐵𝑡
𝑓
when expressed in domestic
currency (𝐵𝑡
𝑓
𝑆𝑡) and discounted by the domestic
money account 𝐵𝑡
𝑑
is a martingale under the domestic
(discounting) risk neutral measure ℙ̃ 𝑑.
 There exits a probability measure measure ℙ̃
equivalent to ℙ on (Ω, 𝔽 𝑇∗̃ ) such that the the foreign
zero coupon bond 𝐵 𝑓(𝑡, 𝑇) when expressed in
domestic currency (𝐵 𝑓(𝑡, 𝑇)𝑆𝑡) and discounted by
the domestic money account 𝐵𝑡
𝑑
is a martingale under
the domestic (discounting) risk neutral measure ℙ̃ 𝑑.
Using the 𝐼𝑡𝑜̃ product and quotient rules, we have
𝜕(𝐵𝑡
𝑓
𝑆𝑡)/𝐵𝑡
𝑑
(𝐵𝑡
𝑓
𝑆𝑡)/𝐵𝑡
𝑑
=
𝜕𝐵𝑡
𝑓
𝐵𝑡
𝑓
+
𝜕𝑆𝑡
𝑆𝑡
−
𝜕𝐵𝑡
𝑑
𝐵𝑡
𝑑
+ 𝑐𝑜𝑣𝑎𝑟𝑖𝑎𝑛𝑐𝑒 𝑡𝑒𝑟𝑚𝑠⏟
=0
treated as an non-increasing function with 𝑆𝑡 > 0 for any
𝑡 and 𝑆0 = 1.
 On HJM Model and Its Extension to Single-Currency-Multiple-Curves Modelling
Page 8 of 13
= 𝑟𝑡
𝑓
𝑑𝑡 + 𝜇 𝑡 𝑑𝑡 + 𝜎𝑡
𝑠
𝑑 − 𝑟𝑡
𝑑
𝑑𝑡
= 𝜎𝑡
𝑠
(𝜃𝑡 𝑑𝑡 + 𝑑𝑊̃ 𝑆(𝑡))
where
𝜃𝑡 =
𝑟𝑡
𝑓
− 𝑟𝑡
𝑑
+ 𝜇 𝑡
𝜎𝑡
𝑠
is the market price of risk satisfying condition (I). By the
Girsanov’s Theorem in (15), we have
𝑊̃ 𝑆
𝑑
(𝑡) = 𝑊̃ 𝑆(𝑡) − ∫ 𝜃 𝑢
𝑡
0
𝑑𝑢 ∀ 𝑡 ∈ [0, 𝑇∗
]
and
𝜕(𝐵𝑡
𝑓
𝑆𝑡)/𝐵𝑡
𝑑
(𝐵𝑡
𝑓
𝑆𝑡)/𝐵𝑡
𝑑
= 𝜎𝑡
𝑠
𝑑𝑊̃ 𝑆
𝑑
(𝑡)
(34)
Multiplying equation (34) by 𝐵𝑡
𝑑
/𝐵𝑡
𝑓
and by the 𝐼𝑡𝑜̃
rules, we have the dynamics of the spot “exchange” rate
under the domestic (discounting) risk neutral measure ℙ̃ 𝑑
𝜕𝑆𝑡
𝑆𝑡
= (𝑟𝑡
𝑑
− 𝑟𝑡
𝑓
)𝑑𝑡 + 𝜎𝑡
𝑠
𝑑𝑊̃ 𝑆
𝑑
(𝑡)
= [𝑓 𝑑
(𝑡, 𝑡) − 𝑓 𝑓
(𝑡, 𝑡)]𝑑𝑡 + 𝜎𝑡
𝑠
𝑑𝑊̃ 𝑆
𝑑
(𝑡)
(35)
Similarly, for the foreign bond process, we have
𝜕(𝐵 𝑓(𝑡, 𝑇)𝑆𝑡)/𝐵𝑡
𝑑
(𝐵 𝑓(𝑡, 𝑇)𝑆𝑡)/𝐵𝑡
𝑑
=
𝜕𝐵 𝑓(𝑡, 𝑇)
𝐵 𝑓(𝑡, 𝑇)
+
𝜕𝑆𝑡
𝑆𝑡
+
𝜕[𝐵 𝑓(𝑡, 𝑇), 𝑆𝑡]
𝐵 𝑓(𝑡, 𝑇)𝑆𝑡
−
𝜕𝐵𝑡
𝑑
𝐵𝑡
𝑑 + 𝑐𝑜𝑣𝑎𝑟𝑖𝑎𝑛𝑐𝑒 𝑡𝑒𝑟𝑚𝑠⏟
=0
= 𝑟𝑡
𝑓
𝑑𝑡 − Σ 𝑓(𝑡, 𝑇)𝑑𝑊̃ 𝑓(𝑡) + (𝑟𝑡
𝑑
− 𝑟𝑡
𝑓
)𝑑𝑡 + 𝜎𝑡
𝑠
𝑑𝑊̃𝑠
𝑑
(𝑡)
− Σ 𝑓(𝑡, 𝑇)𝑑𝑊̃ 𝑓(𝑡)𝜎𝑡
𝑠
𝑑𝑊̃𝑠
𝑑
(𝑡) − 𝑟𝑡
𝑑
𝑑𝑡
= −Σ 𝑓(𝑡, 𝑇) 𝜎𝑡
𝑠
𝜌𝑡
𝐵 𝑓,𝑠
𝑑𝑡 − Σ 𝑓(𝑡, 𝑇)𝑑𝑊̃𝑓 (𝑡) + 𝜎𝑡
𝑠
𝑑𝑊̃𝑠
𝑑(𝑡)
(36)
where 〈𝑊̃ 𝑓, 𝑊̃ 𝑆
𝑑
〉 = 𝜌𝑡
𝐵 𝑓,𝑠
is the instantaneous correlation
between relative changes in 𝐵 𝑓(∙, 𝑇) and 𝑆. Moreover,
using the fact that the sum of two martingales under ℙ̃ 𝑑 is
a martingale under ℙ̃ 𝑑 , we can derive the Brownian
motion of the foreign bond process in the domestic
measure as
𝑊̃𝑓
𝑑
(𝑡) = 𝑊̃𝑓(𝑡) + ∫ 𝜎 𝑢
𝑠
𝜌 𝑢
𝐵 𝑓,𝑠
𝑡
0
𝑑𝑢 ∀ 𝑡 ∈ [0, 𝑇∗
]
7
From German et al. (1995), Musiela and Rutkowski
(2005), and Shreve (2004), the forward price of an asset is
Thus,
𝜕𝐵 𝑓(𝑡, 𝑇)
𝐵 𝑓(𝑡, 𝑇)
= [𝑟𝑡
𝑓
+ Σ 𝑓(𝑡, 𝑇)𝜎𝑡
𝑠
𝜌𝑡
𝐵 𝑓,𝑠
] 𝑑𝑡 − Σ 𝑓(𝑡, 𝑇)𝑑𝑊̃ 𝑓
𝑑
(𝑡)
(37)
and the dynamics of the foreign (forwarding) forward
curve in domestic (discounting) measure can be derived by
solving equation (37) for ln 𝐵(𝑡, 𝑇) and by equation (1),
namely
𝑓 𝑓(𝑡, 𝑇) = − 𝜕 𝑇 ln 𝐵 𝑓(𝑡, 𝑇)
where
𝜕 ln 𝐵 𝑓(𝑡, 𝑇) = (𝑟𝑡
𝑓
+ Σ 𝑓(𝑡, 𝑇)𝜎𝑡
𝑠
𝜌𝑡
𝐵 𝑓,𝑠
−
1
2
|Σ 𝑓(𝑡, 𝑇)|
2
) 𝑑𝑡
− Σ 𝑓(𝑡, 𝑇)𝑑𝑊̃ 𝑓
𝑑
(𝑡)
and
ln 𝐵 𝑓(𝑡, 𝑇) = ln 𝐵 𝑓(0, 𝑇) +
∫ (
(𝑟𝑢
𝑓
+ Σ 𝑓(𝑢, 𝑇)𝜎 𝑢
𝑠
𝜌 𝑢
𝐵 𝑓,𝑠
−
1
2
|Σ 𝑓(𝑢, 𝑇)|
2
) 𝑑𝑢
− Σ 𝑓(𝑢, 𝑇)𝑑𝑊̃𝑓
𝑑
(𝑢)
)
𝑡
0
and
𝑓 𝑓(𝑡, 𝑇) = 𝑓 𝑓(0, 𝑇) − ∫ (𝜎 𝑓(𝑢, 𝑇) ∫ 𝜎 𝑓(𝑢, 𝑠)𝑑𝑠 +
𝑇
𝑡
𝑡
0
𝜎 𝑓(𝑢, 𝑇)𝜎 𝑢
𝑠
𝜌 𝑢
𝐵 𝑓,𝑠
) 𝑑𝑢 + ∫ 𝜎 𝑓(𝑢, 𝑇)𝑑𝑊̃𝑓
𝑑
(𝑢)
𝑡
0
(38)
which is the instantaneous forward rate for the forwarding
curve under the discounting risk-neutral probability
measure ℙ̃ 𝑑. From Martinez (2009) and Grbac and
Runggaldier (2015), the HJM drift condition in equation
(38) under ℙ̃ 𝑑 can be derived directly by
𝜕 𝑇 [−⋀ 𝑓(𝑡, 𝑇) +
1
2
|Σ 𝑓(𝑡, 𝑇)|
2
] = 𝜕 𝑇[〈 𝜎𝑡
𝑠
, Σ 𝑓(𝑡, 𝑇)〉]
(39)
4.3 Forward Measure
As with many derivatives such as FX options, FRAs are
written on the forward rates instead of spot rates. Hence,
in order to price a forward contract under the no-arbitrage
framework, we need to apply the forward probability
measure7
. Recall that we are interested in calculating the
expectation in (29), namely
𝔼 𝑡
ℙ̃
𝑑
𝑇+𝛿
(𝐿(𝑇, 𝑇 + 𝛿)|ℱ𝑡) = 𝔼 𝑡
ℙ̃
𝑑
𝑇+𝛿
(𝐹𝑓(𝑇, 𝑇, 𝑇 + 𝛿)|ℱ𝑡)
which allows one to price the FRA in a single-currency-
double-curves framework at time 𝑡 for settlement date
a martingale under the forward probability measure
associated with the settlement date of the forward contract.
 On HJM Model and Its Extension to Single-Currency-Multiple-Curves Modelling
Page 9 of 13
𝑇 + 𝛿 using the artificial risky bonds 𝐵 𝑓(𝑡, ∙ ) and the
spot “exchange” rate 𝑆𝑡.
From Musiela and Rutkowski (2005), the forward
process of the zero bonds for the time interval [𝑇, 𝑇 + 𝛿]
is given by
𝐹𝐵(𝑡, 𝑇, 𝑇 + 𝛿) ≝
𝐵(𝑡, 𝑇)
𝐵(𝑡, 𝑇 + 𝛿)
∀ 𝑡 ∈ [0, 𝑇]
(40)
and the 𝑥 - 𝑇 + 𝛿 - forward prices are martingales under
the 𝑥 - 𝑇 + 𝛿 - forward measure ℙ̃ 𝑥
𝑇+𝛿
, 𝑥 = {𝑑, 𝑓}. By
𝐼𝑡𝑜̃ quotient rule, we have
𝐹𝐵
𝑥
(𝑡, 𝑇, 𝑇 + 𝛿) =
𝜕(𝐵 𝑥(𝑡, 𝑇)/𝐵 𝑥(𝑡, 𝑇 + 𝛿))
𝐵 𝑥(𝑡, 𝑇)/𝐵 𝑥(𝑡, 𝑇 + 𝛿)
=
𝜕𝐵 𝑥(𝑡, 𝑇)
𝐵 𝑥(𝑡, 𝑇)
−
𝜕𝐵 𝑥(𝑡, 𝑇 + 𝛿)
𝐵 𝑥(𝑡, 𝑇 + 𝛿)
+
𝜕[𝐵 𝑥(𝑡, 𝑇 + 𝛿), 𝐵 𝑥(𝑡, 𝑇 + 𝛿)]
(𝐵 𝑥(𝑡, 𝑇 + 𝛿))
2
−
𝜕[𝐵 𝑥(𝑡, 𝑇), 𝐵 𝑥(𝑡, 𝑇 + 𝛿)]
𝐵 𝑥(𝑡, 𝑇)𝐵 𝑥(𝑡, 𝑇 + 𝛿)
= (Σ 𝑥(𝑡, 𝑇 + 𝛿) − Σ 𝑥(𝑡, 𝑇))𝑑𝑊̃𝑥
𝑥(𝑡)
+(|Σ 𝑥(𝑡, 𝑇 + 𝛿)|2
− Σ 𝑥(𝑡, 𝑇)Σ 𝑥(𝑡, 𝑇 + 𝛿))𝑑𝑡
(41)
which we assumed, for simplicity, that the forward
volatilities (Σ 𝑥(𝑡, 𝑇 + 𝛿) − Σ 𝑥(𝑡, 𝑇)) are bounded.
The drift term in equation (41) is not equal zero because
𝑊̃𝑥
𝑥
(𝑡) is a Brownian motion under the 𝑥 - risk-neutral
measure instead of a Brownian motion under x - 𝑇 + 𝛿
forward measure ℙ̃ 𝑥
𝑇+𝛿
. Therefore, the 𝑅𝑎𝑑𝑜𝑛 -
𝑁𝑖𝑘𝑜𝑑𝑦́ 𝑚 𝑑𝑒𝑟𝑖𝑣𝑎𝑡𝑖𝑣𝑒 gives
𝜕ℙ̃ 𝑥
𝑇+𝛿
𝜕ℙ̃ 𝑥
=
exp (− ∫ 𝑟𝑢
𝑥
𝑑𝑢
𝑇+𝛿
0
)
𝐵 𝑥(0, 𝑇 + 𝛿)
=
1
𝐵 𝑥(0, 𝑇 + 𝛿)𝐵 𝑇+𝛿
𝑥
= ℇ 𝑇+𝛿 (− ∫ Σ 𝑥(𝑢, 𝑇 + 𝛿)
∙
0
𝑑𝑊̃𝑥
𝑥
(𝑢)) ℙ̃ 𝑥 − 𝑎. 𝑠.
(42)
(Musiela and Rutkowski, 1997; Shreve, 2004)
which implies that moving to the 𝑥 - 𝑇 + 𝛿 - forward
measure on (Ω, 𝔽 𝑇+𝛿) amounts to changing the numeraire
from the saving account 𝐵 𝑇+𝛿
𝑥
to the zero-coupon bond
𝐵 𝑥(0, 𝑇 + 𝛿). Moreover, by Girsanov’s Theorem
𝑊̃𝑥
𝑥,𝑇+𝛿
(𝑡) = 𝑊̃𝑥
𝑥(𝑡) + ∫ Σ 𝑥(𝑢, 𝑇 + 𝛿)𝑑𝑢
𝑡
0
(43)
which gives the Brownian motion under the 𝑥 - forward
martingale measure for the settlement date 𝑇 + 𝛿
associated with the 𝑥 - 𝑇 + 𝛿 - maturity zero-coupon bond
as a numeraire.
From Musiela and Rutkowski (1997), the above
derivations satisfy the no-arbitrage condition if the
forward bond processes 𝐹𝐵(𝑡, 𝑇, 𝑇 + 𝛿) > 1, otherwise
the processes are said to satisfy the weak no-arbitrage
condition. Nevertheless, the 𝑥 zero bonds under the 𝑥 -
𝑇 + 𝛿 - forward martingale measure can be summarized as
follows
𝜕𝐵 𝑓(𝑡, 𝑇)
𝐵 𝑓(𝑡, 𝑇)
= (𝑟𝑡
𝑓
+ Σ 𝑓(𝑡, 𝑇)Σ 𝑓(𝑡, 𝑇 + 𝛿)) 𝑑𝑡
− Σ 𝑓(𝑡, 𝑇)𝑑𝑊̃𝑓
𝑓,𝑇+𝛿
(𝑡)
(44)
𝜕𝐵 𝑑(𝑡, 𝑇 + 𝛿)
𝐵 𝑑(𝑡, 𝑇 + 𝛿)
= (𝑟𝑡
𝑑
+ |Σ 𝑑(𝑡, 𝑇 + 𝛿)|2)𝑑𝑡
− Σ 𝑑(𝑡, 𝑇 + 𝛿)𝑑𝑊̃𝑑
𝑑,𝑇+𝛿
(𝑡)
(45)
Before devolving into the dynamics of the foreign
(forwarding) curve, let us first consider a foreign exchange
forward contact written at time 𝑡 for settlement at time 𝑇.
By the interest rate parity, the interest rate differential
between the domestic and foreign economies must equal
to the difference between the forward exchange rate and
spot exchange rate. Therefore, we have the forward
exchange rate given by
𝐹𝑆(𝑡, 𝑇) = e(𝑟 𝑑−𝑟 𝑓)(𝑇−𝑡)
𝑆𝑡
=
𝐵 𝑓(𝑡, 𝑇)
𝐵 𝑑(𝑡, 𝑇)
𝑆𝑡 ∀ 𝑡 ∈ [0, 𝑇]
(46)
Forward FX-rate (Musiela and Rutkowski, 2005:p.155)
Applying this analogy to our case, we are interested in
deriving a forward process that is consistent with the
expectation in (29), namely a forward “exchange” rate
𝐹𝑆(𝑡, 𝑇, 𝑇 + 𝛿) at time 𝑡 for the time interval [𝑡, 𝑇] and for
settlement date 𝑇 + 𝛿. Accordingly, one is naturally led to
look at the ratio
𝐹𝑆(𝑡, 𝑇, 𝑇 + 𝛿) =
𝐵 𝑓(𝑡, 𝑇)
𝐵 𝑑(𝑡, 𝑇 + 𝛿)
𝑆𝑡 ∀ 𝑡 ∈ [0, 𝑇]
(47)
This derivation follows directly from the 𝑅𝑎𝑑𝑜𝑛 -
𝑁𝑖𝑘𝑜𝑑𝑦́ 𝑚 𝑑𝑒𝑟𝑖𝑣𝑎𝑡𝑖𝑣𝑒 in (42) that under the domestic
(discounting) - 𝑇 + 𝛿 - forward measure, the forward
“exchange” rate associated to the numeraire 𝐵 𝑑(𝑡, 𝑇 + 𝛿)
is a martingale under ℙ̃ 𝑑
𝑇+𝛿
, assuming that 𝐵 𝑓(𝑡, 𝑇)𝑆𝑡 is a
domestic tradable asset. Yet, before deriving the dynamics
of equation (47), let us first change the measure of the spot
“exchange” rate 𝑆𝑡 under ℙ̃ 𝑑 to ℙ̃ 𝑑
𝑇+𝛿
𝜕(𝑆𝑡 𝐵𝑡
𝑓
)/𝐵 𝑑(𝑡, 𝑇 + 𝛿)
(𝑆𝑡 𝐵𝑡
𝑓
)/𝐵 𝑑(𝑡, 𝑇 + 𝛿)
=
𝜕𝑆𝑡
𝑆𝑡
+
𝜕𝐵𝑡
𝑓
𝐵𝑡
𝑓
−
𝜕𝐵 𝑑(𝑡, 𝑇 + 𝛿)
𝐵 𝑑(𝑡, 𝑇 + 𝛿)
+
[𝜕𝐵 𝑑(𝑡, 𝑇 + 𝛿)]2
(𝐵 𝑑(𝑡, 𝑇 + 𝛿))
2 −
𝜕𝑆𝑡 𝐵𝑡
𝑓
𝑆𝑡 𝐵𝑡
𝑓
𝜕𝐵 𝑑(𝑡, 𝑇 + 𝛿)
𝐵 𝑑(𝑡, 𝑇 + 𝛿)
= (𝑟𝑡
𝑑
− 𝑟𝑡
𝑓
)𝑑𝑡 + 𝜎𝑡
𝑠
𝑑𝑊̃ 𝑆
𝑑
(𝑡) + 𝑟𝑡
𝑓
𝑑𝑡
− (𝑟𝑡
𝑑
+ |Σ 𝑑(𝑡, 𝑇 + 𝛿)|2)𝑑𝑡
+ Σ 𝑑(𝑡, 𝑇 + 𝛿)𝑑𝑊̃ 𝑑
𝑑,𝑇+𝛿
(𝑡)
+ |Σ 𝑑(𝑡, 𝑇 + 𝛿)|2
𝑑𝑡
+ 𝜌𝑡
𝐵 𝑑,𝑆
𝜎𝑡
𝑠
Σ 𝑑(𝑡, 𝑇 + 𝛿)𝑑𝑡
 On HJM Model and Its Extension to Single-Currency-Multiple-Curves Modelling
Page 10 of 13
= 𝜎𝑡
𝑠
(𝑑𝑊̃ 𝑆
𝑑
(𝑡) + {𝜌𝑡
𝐵 𝑑,𝑆
Σ 𝑑(𝑡, 𝑇 + 𝛿)} 𝑑𝑡)
+ Σ 𝑑(𝑡, 𝑇 + 𝛿)𝑑𝑊̃ 𝑑
𝑑,𝑇+𝛿
(𝑡)
we therefore have
𝑊̃𝑆
𝑑,𝑇+𝛿
(𝑡) = 𝑊̃ 𝑆
𝑑
(𝑡) + ∫ 𝜌 𝑢
𝐵 𝑑,𝑆
Σ 𝑑(𝑢, 𝑇 + 𝛿)
𝑡
0
𝑑𝑢
and the spot “exchange” rate 𝑆𝑡 under the domestic
(discounting) - 𝑇 + 𝛿 - forward measure
𝜕𝑆𝑡
𝑆𝑡
= (𝑟𝑡
𝑑
− 𝑟𝑡
𝑓
− 𝜌𝑡
𝐵 𝑑,𝑆
𝜎𝑡
𝑠
Σ 𝑑(𝑡, 𝑇 + 𝛿))𝑑𝑡 + 𝜎𝑡
𝑠
𝑑𝑊̃𝑠
𝑑,𝑇+𝛿
(𝑡)
(48)
Following from above, we can derive the forward
process for 𝐹𝑆(𝑡, 𝑇, 𝑇 + 𝛿) as
𝜕(𝑆𝑡 𝐵 𝑓(𝑡, 𝑇))/𝐵 𝑑(𝑡, 𝑇 + 𝛿)
(𝑆𝑡 𝐵 𝑓(𝑡, 𝑇))/𝐵 𝑑(𝑡, 𝑇 + 𝛿)
= (𝑟𝑡
𝑑
− 𝑟𝑡
𝑓
− 𝜌𝑡
𝐵 𝑑,𝑆
𝜎𝑡
𝑠
Σ 𝑑(𝑡, 𝑇 + 𝛿)) 𝑑𝑡
+𝜎𝑡
𝑠
𝑑𝑊̃𝑠
𝑑,𝑇+𝛿
(𝑡)
+ (𝑟𝑡
𝑓
+ Σ 𝑓(𝑡, 𝑇)Σ 𝑓(𝑡, 𝑇 + 𝛿)) 𝑑𝑡
− Σ 𝑓(𝑡, 𝑇)𝑑𝑊̃𝑓
𝑓,𝑇+𝛿
(𝑡)
− (𝑟𝑡
𝑑
+ |Σ 𝑑(𝑡, 𝑇 + 𝛿)|2)𝑑𝑡
+ Σ 𝑑(𝑡, 𝑇 + 𝛿)𝑑𝑊̃𝑑
𝑑,𝑇+𝛿
(𝑡)
+ |Σ 𝑑(𝑡, 𝑇 + 𝛿)|2
𝑑𝑡
− Σ 𝑓(𝑡, 𝑇)𝜎𝑡
𝑠
𝜌𝑡
𝐵 𝑓,𝑆
𝑑𝑡
+ Σ 𝑓(𝑡, 𝑇)Σ 𝑑(𝑡, 𝑇 + 𝛿)𝜌𝑡
𝐵 𝑑,𝐵 𝑓
𝑑𝑡
+ 𝜌𝑡
𝐵 𝑑,𝑆
𝜎𝑡
𝑠
Σ 𝑑(𝑡, 𝑇 + 𝛿)
= −Σ 𝑓(𝑡, 𝑇)( 𝑑𝑊̃𝑓
𝑓,𝑇+𝛿
(𝑡)
− {(Σ 𝑓(𝑡, 𝑇 + 𝛿) + Σ 𝑑(𝑡, 𝑇 + 𝛿)𝜌𝑡
𝐵 𝑑,𝐵 𝑓
− 𝜎𝑡
𝑠
𝜌𝑡
𝐵 𝑓,𝑆
) 𝑑𝑡}
+ Σ 𝑑(𝑡, 𝑇 + 𝛿)𝑑𝑊̃𝑑
𝑑,𝑇+𝛿
(𝑡)
+ 𝜎𝑡
𝑠
𝑑𝑊̃𝑠
𝑑,𝑇+𝛿
(𝑡)
which implies
𝜕ℙ̃ 𝑓
𝑑,𝑇+𝛿
𝜕ℙ̃
𝑓
𝑓,𝑇+𝛿
=
ℇ 𝑇+𝛿 (− ∫ {
Σ 𝑓(𝑢, 𝑇 + 𝛿)
+Σ 𝑑(𝑢, 𝑇 + 𝛿)𝜌 𝑢
𝐵 𝑑,𝐵 𝑓
−𝜎 𝑢
𝑠
𝜌 𝑢
𝐵 𝑓,𝑆
𝑑𝑊̃𝑓
𝑓,𝑇+𝛿
(𝑢)
}
∙
0
) ℙ̃ 𝑓
𝑓,𝑇+𝛿
− 𝑎. 𝑠.
(49)
and
𝑊̃𝑓
𝑑,𝑇+𝛿
(𝑡) = 𝑊̃𝑓
𝑓,𝑇+𝛿
(𝑡)
− ∫ (Σ 𝑓(𝑢, 𝑇 + 𝛿) + Σ 𝑑(𝑢, 𝑇 + 𝛿)𝜌 𝑢
𝐵 𝑑,𝐵 𝑓
− 𝜎 𝑢
𝑠
𝜌 𝑢
𝐵 𝑓,𝑆
)
𝑡
0
𝑑𝑢
(50)
where 𝑊̃𝑓
𝑑,𝑇+𝛿
(𝑡) is the Brownian motion of the foreign
(forwarding) bond under the domestic (discounting) - 𝑇 +
𝛿 - forward measure.
Hence, the foreign (reference) bond process under ℙ̃ 𝑑
𝑇+𝛿
is
𝜕𝐵 𝑓(𝑡, 𝑇)
𝐵 𝑓(𝑡, 𝑇)
= (𝑟𝑡
𝑓
− Σ 𝑓(𝑡, 𝑇) {Σ 𝑑(𝑡, 𝑇 + 𝛿)𝜌𝑡
𝐵 𝑑,𝐵 𝑓
− 𝜎𝑡
𝑠
𝜌𝑡
𝐵 𝑓,𝑆
}) 𝑑𝑡 − Σ 𝑓(𝑡, 𝑇)𝑑𝑊̃𝑓
𝑑,𝑇+𝛿
(𝑡)
(51)
Solving equation (51) for ln 𝐵 𝑓(𝑡, 𝑇) and
differentiating with respect to 𝑇, 𝜕 𝑇 ln 𝐵 𝑓(𝑡, 𝑇), would
give the dynamics of the instantaneous forward rate
process for the forwarding curve 𝑓 𝑓( ∙ , 𝑇) under ℙ̃ 𝑑
𝑇+𝛿
.
However, such derivation is not necessary as we could
price the FRA in term of a quanto correction – a procedure
typical to the pricing of cross-currency derivatives.
4.3 Pricing Under Single-Currency-Double Curves
Having derived the 𝑅𝑎𝑑𝑜𝑛 - 𝑁𝑖𝑘𝑜𝑑𝑦́ 𝑚 𝑑𝑒𝑛𝑠𝑖𝑡𝑦 in
equation (49), we can proceed to calculate the expectation
in (29). In a single-currency-double-curves framework,
this amounts to transforming a cash-flow on the
forwarding curve to the corresponding discounting curve
(Bianchetti, 2009). Thus, we have the Libor rate given by
the following
𝔼 𝑡
ℙ̃ 𝑑
𝑇+𝛿
(𝐿(𝑇, 𝑇 + 𝛿)) = 𝔼 𝑡
ℙ̃ 𝑑
𝑇+𝛿
(𝐹𝑓(𝑇, 𝑇, 𝑇 + 𝛿))
=
1
𝛿
(𝔼 𝑡
ℙ̃
𝑑
𝑇+𝛿
[
𝐵 𝑓(𝑡, 𝑇)
𝐵 𝑓(𝑡, 𝑇 + 𝛿)
] − 1)
=
1
𝛿
(𝔼 𝑡
ℙ̃
𝑑
𝑇+𝛿
[𝐹𝐵
𝑓
(𝑇, 𝑇, 𝑇 + 𝛿)] − 1)
(52)
From (41) and (50), under the domestic (discounting)
forward measure, we have the foreign (forwarding)
forward bond price given by
𝜕𝐹𝐵
𝑓
(𝑡, 𝑇, 𝑇 + 𝛿)
= (Σ 𝑓(𝑡, 𝑇 + 𝛿) − Σ 𝑓(𝑡, 𝑇)) 𝑑𝑊̃𝑓
𝑓,𝑇+𝛿
(𝑡)
= (Σ 𝑓(𝑡, 𝑇 + 𝛿) − Σ 𝑓(𝑡, 𝑇))
{𝑑𝑊̃𝑓
𝑑,𝑇+𝛿
(𝑡) + (
Σ 𝑓(𝑡, 𝑇 + 𝛿) +
Σ 𝑑(𝑡, 𝑇 + 𝛿)𝜌𝑡
𝐵 𝑑,𝐵 𝑓
− 𝜎𝑡
𝑠
𝜌𝑡
𝐵 𝑓,𝑆
) 𝑑𝑡}
(53)
and
𝔼 𝑡
ℙ̃
𝑑
𝑇+𝛿
(𝐹𝐵
𝑓
(𝑇, 𝑇, 𝑇 + 𝛿)) = 𝐹𝐵
𝑓
(𝑡, 𝑇, 𝑇 + 𝛿) 𝑒𝑥𝑝
(
∫
(
(Σ 𝑓(𝑢, 𝑇 + 𝛿) − Σ 𝑓(𝑢, 𝑇))
{(
Σ 𝑓(𝑢, 𝑇 + 𝛿) + Σ 𝑑(𝑢, 𝑇 + 𝛿)𝜌 𝑢
𝐵 𝑑,𝐵 𝑓
−𝜎 𝑢
𝑠
𝜌 𝑢
𝐵 𝑓,𝑆
)}
)
𝑇
𝑡
𝑑𝑢
)⏟
𝑄𝑢𝑎𝑛𝑡𝑜 𝑐𝑜𝑟𝑟𝑒𝑐𝑡𝑖𝑜𝑛
(54)
 On HJM Model and Its Extension to Single-Currency-Multiple-Curves Modelling
Page 11 of 13
Hence,
𝔼 𝑡
ℙ̃
𝑑
𝑇+𝛿
(𝐿(𝑇, 𝑇 + 𝛿)) = (1 + 𝛿 𝐹𝑓
𝑀
(𝑡, 𝑇, 𝑇 + 𝛿)) 𝑒𝑥𝑝
(
∫
(
(Σ 𝑓(𝑢, 𝑇 + 𝛿) − Σ 𝑓(𝑢, 𝑇))
{(
Σ 𝑓(𝑢, 𝑇 + 𝛿) + Σ 𝑑(𝑢, 𝑇 + 𝛿)𝜌 𝑢
𝐵 𝑑,𝐵 𝑓
−𝜎 𝑢
𝑠
𝜌 𝑢
𝐵 𝑓,𝑆
)}
)
𝑇
𝑡
𝑑𝑢
)
− 1
(55)
where 𝐹𝑓
𝑀
(𝑡, 𝑇, 𝑇 + 𝛿) denotes the Libor rate for period
{𝑇, 𝑇 + 𝛿}, observable at time t from market data.
As shown in the above derivations, the expectation of
𝐹𝐵
𝑓
(𝑇, 𝑇, 𝑇 + 𝛿) has a quanto correction, which depends
on the implied forward bond price volatilities and two
correlation terms. This means that the FRA can be priced
by discounting the cash-flow with the risk-free discount
rate and adding a convexity adjustment factor – a
procedure typical to the pricing of cross-currency products.
Furthermore, one could simplify the derivations and
obtain results similar to Bianchetti (2009) and Theis (2017)
by modelling the quantity 𝐹𝑆(𝑡, 𝑇, 𝑇 + 𝛿) directly, and
changing the measure of 𝐹𝐵
𝑓
(𝑡, 𝑇, 𝑇 + 𝛿) to ℙ̃ 𝑑
𝑇+𝛿
.
Following from our foreign currency analogy and from
Cuchiero, Fontana and Gnoatto (2014), let us consider the
forward “exchange” rate for the time intervals [𝑡, 𝑇] and
[𝑡, 𝑇 + 𝛿]
𝐹𝑆(𝑡, 𝑇) =
𝐵 𝑓(𝑡, 𝑇)𝑆𝑡
𝐵 𝑑(𝑡, 𝑇)
and
𝐹𝑆(𝑡, 𝑇 + 𝛿) =
𝐵 𝑓(𝑡, 𝑇 + 𝛿)𝑆𝑡
𝐵 𝑑(𝑡, 𝑇 + 𝛿)
The forward interest rate spread8
𝐹𝑆(𝑡, 𝑇, 𝑇 + 𝛿) can
be derived by
𝐹𝑆(𝑡, 𝑇 + 𝛿)
𝐹𝑆(𝑡, 𝑇)
=
𝐵 𝑓(𝑡, 𝑇 + 𝛿)𝑆𝑡
𝐵 𝑑(𝑡, 𝑇 + 𝛿)
𝐵 𝑑(𝑡, 𝑇)
𝐵 𝑓(𝑡, 𝑇)𝑆𝑡
From equation (46), we thus have
𝐹𝑆(𝑡, 𝑇, 𝑇 + 𝛿)𝐹𝐵
𝑓
(𝑡, 𝑇, 𝑇 + 𝛿) = 𝐹𝐵
𝑑
(𝑡, 𝑇, 𝑇 + 𝛿)
(56)
Notice, however, that different dynamics can be
specified according to different interpretation of the
quantity 𝐹𝑆(𝑡, 𝑇, 𝑇 + 𝛿). While Bianchetti (2009) and
Theis (2017) use an FX analogy, Henrard (2010),
Mercurio (2010), and Mercurio and Xie (2012) model it as
a stochastic basis spread. Here we shall continue with our
foreign exchange analogy and model 𝐹𝑆(𝑡, 𝑇, 𝑇 + 𝛿) as
forward “exchange” rate consistent with equation (47),
hence,
8
See Cuchiero, Fontana and Gnoatto (2014) Appendix B
for proof and derivation.
𝐹𝑆(𝑡, 𝑇, 𝑇 + 𝛿) = 𝜎𝑡
𝑠
𝑑𝑊̃𝑠
𝑑,𝑇+𝛿
(𝑡) − Σ 𝑓(𝑡, 𝑇)𝑑𝑊̃𝑓
𝑑,𝑇+𝛿
(𝑡)
+ Σ 𝑑(𝑡, 𝑇 + 𝛿)𝑑𝑊̃𝑑
𝑑,𝑇+𝛿
(𝑡)
(57)
which is a martingale under ℙ̃ 𝑑
𝑇+𝛿
. Combining the forward
“exchange” rate process into a single Brownian motion,
we have
𝐹𝑆(𝑡, 𝑇, 𝑇 + 𝛿) = 𝜎𝑡
𝐹𝑠
𝑑𝑊̃𝐹𝑠
𝑑,𝑇+𝛿
(𝑡)
(58)
where
𝜎𝑡
𝐹𝑠
𝑑𝑊̃𝐹𝑠
𝑑,𝑇+𝛿
(𝑡) = 𝜎𝑡
𝑠
𝑑𝑊̃𝑠
𝑑,𝑇+𝛿
(𝑡) − Σ 𝑓(𝑡, 𝑇)𝑑𝑊̃𝑓
𝑑,𝑇+𝛿
(𝑡)
+ Σ 𝑑(𝑡, 𝑇 + 𝛿)𝑑𝑊̃ 𝑑
𝑑,𝑇+𝛿
(𝑡)
(59)
From the no-arbitrage conditions, we know that the
process {𝐹𝑆(𝑡, 𝑇, 𝑇 + 𝛿)𝐹𝐵
𝑓
(𝑡, 𝑇, 𝑇 + 𝛿)} in (56) is a
martingale under ℙ̃ 𝑑
𝑇+𝛿
. Hence, by 𝐼𝑡𝑜̃ product rule
𝜕𝐹𝑆(𝑡, 𝑇, 𝑇 + 𝛿)𝐹𝐵
𝑓
(𝑡, 𝑇, 𝑇 + 𝛿)
𝐹𝑆(𝑡, 𝑇, 𝑇 + 𝛿)𝐹𝐵
𝑓
(𝑡, 𝑇, 𝑇 + 𝛿)
=
𝜕𝐹𝑆(𝑡, 𝑇, 𝑇 + 𝛿)
𝐹𝑆(𝑡, 𝑇, 𝑇 + 𝛿)
+
𝜕𝐹𝐵
𝑓
(𝑡, 𝑇, 𝑇 + 𝛿)
𝐹𝐵
𝑓
(𝑡, 𝑇, 𝑇 + 𝛿)
+
𝜕𝐹𝑆(𝑡, 𝑇, 𝑇 + 𝛿)
𝐹𝑆(𝑡, 𝑇, 𝑇 + 𝛿)
𝜕𝐹𝐵
𝑓
(𝑡, 𝑇, 𝑇 + 𝛿)
𝐹𝐵
𝑓
(𝑡, 𝑇, 𝑇 + 𝛿)
= 𝜎𝑡
𝐹𝑠
𝑑𝑊̃𝐹𝑠
𝑑,𝑇+𝛿
(𝑡) + (Σ 𝑓(𝑡, 𝑇 + 𝛿) − Σ 𝑓(𝑡, 𝑇)) 𝑑𝑊̃𝑓
𝑓,𝑇+𝛿
(𝑡)
+ (Σ 𝑓(𝑡, 𝑇 + 𝛿) − Σ 𝑓(𝑡, 𝑇)) 𝜎𝑡
𝐹𝑠
𝜌𝑡
𝐵 𝑓,𝐹𝑠
𝑑𝑡
which gives
𝑊̃𝑓
𝑑,𝑇+𝛿
(𝑡) = 𝑊̃𝑓
𝑓,𝑇+𝛿
(𝑡) + ∫ 𝜎 𝑢
𝐹𝑠
𝜌 𝑢
𝐵 𝑓,𝐹𝑠
𝑡
0
𝑑𝑢
(60)
Furthermore, from equation (41) and (60), we can
derive
𝜕𝐹𝐵
𝑓
(𝑡, 𝑇, 𝑇 + 𝛿) = (Σ 𝑓(𝑡, 𝑇 + 𝛿) − Σ 𝑓(𝑡, 𝑇)) 𝑑𝑊̃𝑓
𝑓,𝑇+𝛿
(𝑡)
= (Σ 𝑓(𝑡, 𝑇 + 𝛿) − Σ 𝑓(𝑡, 𝑇)) {𝑑𝑊̃𝑓
𝑑,𝑇+𝛿
(𝑡)
− 𝜎𝑡
𝐹𝑠
𝜌𝑡
𝐵 𝑓,𝐹𝑠
𝑑𝑡}
and thus
𝔼 𝑡
ℙ̃
𝑑
𝑇+𝛿
(𝐿(𝑇, 𝑇 + 𝛿)) = (1 + 𝛿 𝐹𝑓
𝑀
(𝑡, 𝑇, 𝑇 + 𝛿)) 𝑒𝑥𝑝
(
− ∫ ((Σ 𝑓(𝑢, 𝑇 + 𝛿) − Σ 𝑓(𝑢, 𝑇)) 𝜎 𝑢
𝐹𝑠
𝜌 𝑢
𝐵 𝑓,𝐹𝑠
)
𝑇
𝑡
𝑑𝑢
⏟
𝑄𝑢𝑎𝑛𝑡𝑜 𝑐𝑜𝑟𝑟𝑒𝑐𝑡𝑖𝑜𝑛 )
− 1
(61)
 On HJM Model and Its Extension to Single-Currency-Multiple-Curves Modelling
Page 12 of 13
In this derivation, the quanto correction depends on the
implied foreign forward bond price volatility, the implied
forward “exchange” rate volatility and the correlation
between them. Moreover, since in equations (57)-(59) we
have combined the forward “exchange” rate process into
a single Brownian motion, the forward volatility 𝜎𝑡
𝐹𝑠
can
be computed by
𝑉𝑎𝑟𝑡
ℙ̃
𝑑
𝑇+𝛿
(𝐹𝑆(𝑇, 𝑇, 𝑇 + 𝛿)) = ∫ (𝜎𝑡
𝐹𝑠
𝑑𝑊̃𝐹𝑠
𝑑,𝑇+𝛿
(𝑡))
2𝑇
𝑡
(𝜎𝑡
𝐹𝑠
𝑑𝑊̃𝐹𝑠
𝑑,𝑇+𝛿
(𝑡))
2
= (
𝜎𝑡
𝑠
𝑑𝑊̃𝑠
𝑑,𝑇+𝛿
(𝑡)
− Σ 𝑓(𝑡, 𝑇)𝑑𝑊̃𝑓
𝑑,𝑇+𝛿
(𝑡)
+ Σ 𝑑(𝑡, 𝑇 + 𝛿)𝑑𝑊̃𝑑
𝑑,𝑇+𝛿
(𝑡)
)
2
which gives
𝜎𝑡
𝐹𝑠
=
√{
(𝜎𝑡
𝑠)2 − 2𝜎𝑡
𝑠
Σ 𝑓(𝑡, 𝑇)𝜌𝑡
𝐵 𝑓,𝑆
+2𝜎𝑡
𝑠
Σ 𝑑(𝑡, 𝑇 + 𝛿)𝜌𝑡
𝐵 𝑑,𝑆
−2Σ 𝑓(𝑡, 𝑇)Σ 𝑑(𝑡, 𝑇 + 𝛿)𝜌𝑡
𝐵 𝑑,𝐵 𝑓
+|Σ 𝑓(𝑡, 𝑇)|2 + |Σ 𝑑(𝑡, 𝑇 + 𝛿)|2}
(62)
5. Implementation and Estimation
From the above equation, we can see that the implied
volatility of the forward “exchange” rate can be
calculated by integrating over the volatility functions. In
Bianchetti (2009) and Hunter (2017), the spot volatility 𝜎𝑡
𝑠
is taken to be zero as the spot exchange rate9
in a single-
currency-double-curves framework collapses to 1.
In the HJM model, the volatilities Σ 𝑓
and Σ 𝑑
are
stochastic and it would not be possible to estimate the
quanto correction in (54) and (61). Thus, one would need
to assume a Gaussian structure, in which Σ 𝑓
and Σ 𝑑
are
deterministic (Theis, 2017). Nevertheless, the parameters
of the qunato correction in equations (54) and (61) can be
extracted from market data. In particular, the forward
Libor rate volatilities can be derived from quoted cap/floor
options corresponding to the maturity date T and tenor 𝛿.
For 𝜎𝑡
𝐹𝑠
and 𝜌𝑡
𝐵 𝑓,𝐹𝑠
and for other tenors where there are no
options available, one shall resort to historical data
(Bianchetti, 2009). Moreover, using equation (62), one
could also bootstrap out a term structure for 𝜎𝑡
𝐹𝑠
with Σ 𝑓
and Σ 𝑑
extracted from market data. Conversely, since the
forward “exchange” rate in (46) is the exponential of
∫ 𝑓 𝑑(𝑡, 𝑢)𝑑𝑢 − ∫ 𝑓 𝑓(𝑡, 𝑢)𝑑𝑢
∙
𝑡
∙
𝑡
, its volatility and
correlation with the forwarding rates can be implied from
the behaviour of the spread (Theis, 2017).
Having introduced the OIS rates in Section 4, let us
consider the calculation of the OIS rates. An overnight
indexed swap (OIS) is a contract in which two
counterparties exchange a fixed rate 𝐾 with a floating
9
While the spot rate 𝑆𝑡 in Bianchetti (2009) is unspecified,
the spot rate in Morini (2009) using the same analogy is
modelled as survival probability.
compounded overnight rate (i.e. Fed Funds Effective Rate
for US Dollars and EONIA for Euros). From Brigo and
Mercurio (2006) and Cuchiero, Fontana and Gnoatto
(2014), the pricing formula with $1 notional is given by
OIS(𝑡, 𝑇, 𝑇 𝑛
, 𝐾) =
𝐵 𝑂𝐼𝑆(𝑡, 𝑇) − 𝐵 𝑂𝐼𝑆(𝑡, 𝑇 𝑛) − 𝐾𝛿 ∑ 𝐵 𝑂𝐼𝑆(𝑡, 𝑇 𝑖)
𝑛
𝑖=1
where 𝛿 in here is the payment frequency, typically 1-year
for the USD and EUR markets. 𝑇1
, … , 𝑇 𝑛
are the payment
dates and 𝑇 𝑖+1
− 𝑇 𝑖
= 𝛿 for every 𝑖 = 1, … , 𝑛 − 1 .
Moreover, the floating rate received at time 𝑇 𝑖+1
is set at
time 𝑇 𝑖
. Thus at every time 𝑇 𝑖
, one party pays 𝛿𝐾 while
the other party pays 𝛿𝑅 𝑂𝐼𝑆
(𝑇 𝑖
, 𝑇 𝑖+1
) , where
𝑅 𝑂𝐼𝑆
(𝑇 𝑖
, 𝑇 𝑖+1
) is the compounded OIS rate for the period
[𝑇 𝑖
, 𝑇 𝑖+1
] given by
𝑅 𝑂𝐼𝑆(𝑇 𝑖
, 𝑇 𝑖+1) =
𝛿−1
(∏ (1 + (𝑡 𝑗+1
− 𝑡 𝑗)𝑅 𝑂𝐼𝑆(𝑡 𝑗
, 𝑡 𝑗+1)) − 1
𝑘
𝑗=0
)
(63)
and 𝑇 𝑖
= 𝑡0
< 𝑡1
< ⋯ < 𝑡 𝑘
= 𝑇 𝑖+1
denotes the partition
of the period [𝑇 𝑖
, 𝑇 𝑖+1
] into 𝑘 business days and
𝑅 𝑂𝐼𝑆(𝑡 𝑗
, 𝑡 𝑗+1) denotes the respective OIS rates over the
interval [𝑡 𝑗
, 𝑡 𝑗+1
].
OIS compounded rate (Filipovic and Trolle, 2013:p.12)
Thus, the strike 𝐾 or the OIS rate that makes the swap
fair at inception date 𝑡 with maturity date 𝑇 and 𝑛
payment dates is given by
𝑂𝐼𝑆(𝑡, 𝑇, 𝑛) = 𝐾 =
𝐵 𝑂𝐼𝑆
(𝑡, 𝑇) − 𝐵 𝑂𝐼𝑆
(𝑡, 𝑇 𝑛
)
𝛿 ∑ 𝐵 𝑂𝐼𝑆(𝑡, 𝑇 𝑖)𝑛
𝑖=1
(64)
Taking as example one leg of the swap, i.e., one
payment. For 𝑛 = 1 and 𝑇 = 𝑇 𝑗
, equation (64) gives
𝑂𝐼𝑆(𝑡, 𝑇 𝑗
, 𝑛) = 𝐾 =
𝐵 𝑂𝐼𝑆
(𝑡, 𝑇 𝑗
) − 𝐵 𝑂𝐼𝑆
(𝑡, 𝑇 𝑗+1
)
𝛿𝐵 𝑂𝐼𝑆(𝑡, 𝑇 𝑗+1)
(Musiela and Rutkowski, 1997)
Thus, the term structure for the discount rates can be
bootstrapped from market quotes of OIS.
6. Conclusion
We have reviewed the derivations of the classical
single-currency-single-curve HJM model, and how the
credit crisis and the resulting inconsistencies between rates
have forced the market to evolve to a valuation framework
that incorporates multiple yield curves, namely, one for
discounting and one for each Libor tenor. Following a
foreign-currency analogy, we have also derived the
 On HJM Model and Its Extension to Single-Currency-Multiple-Curves Modelling
Page 13 of 13
dynamics of the discounting and forwarding curves. In
particular, we have examined the pricing of FRA under a
single-currency-double-curves valuation framework and a
convexity adjustment factor, typical to the pricing of
cross-currency derivatives, is derived as a result.
Reference:
Ametrano, F. M., and Bianchetti, M. (2013) Everything
You Always Wanted to Know About Multiple Interest
Rate Curve Bootstrapping But Were Afraid To Ask.
Available from: http://ssrn.com/abstract=2219548
Brigo, D., and Mercurio, F. (2006) Interest Rate Models:
Theory and Practice - with Smile, Inflation and Credit.
Springer, Second Edition
Bianchetti, M. (2009) Two Curves, One Price: Pricing ad
Hedging Interest Rate Derivatives Using Different Yield
Curves for Discounting and Forwarding. Available from:
http://ssrn.com/abstract=1334356
Cox, J.C., Ingersoll, J.E., and Ross, S.A. (1985) A theory
of the term structure of interest rates. Econometrica, vol.
53, pp. 385-407
Cuchiero, C., Fontana, C., and Gnoatto, A. (2015) A
general HJM framework for multiple yield curve
modelling. Finance and Stochastics, vol. 20, pp. 267–320.
Available from: https://link.springer.com/article/10.1007/
s00780-016-0291-5
Dothan, L. (1978) On the term structure of interest rates.
Journal of Financial Economics, vol. 6, pp. 59-69.
Available from: https://www.sciencedirect.com/science/
article/pii/0304405X7890020X
Filipovic, D., and Trolle, A. B. (2013) The term structure
of interbank risk. Journal of Financial Economics, vol.109,
pp. 707-733. Available from: http://www.sciencedirect.co
m/science/article/pii/S0304405X13000949
Grbac, Z., and Runggaldier, W.J. (2015). Interest rate
modeling: post-crisis challenges and approaches. Springer,
First Edition
Ho, T.S.Y., and Lee, S.B. (1986) Term structure
movements and pricing interest rate contingent claims.
Journal of Finance, vol. 41, pp. 1011-1029. Available from:
http://www.jstor.org/stable/2328161?seq=1#page_scan_t
ab_contents
Hull, J., and White, A. (1990). Pricing interest rate
derivatives securities. The Review of Financial Studies,
vol. 3 pp. 573–592. Available from: https://doi.org/10.10
93/rfs/3.4.573
Heath, D., Jarrow, R., and Morton, A. (1992) Bond pricing
and the term structure of interest rates: a new methodology
for contingent claims valuation. Econometrica, vol. 60, pp.
77-105
Henrard, M. (2007). The Irony in the Derivatives
Discounting. Wilmott Magazine, pp. 92-98
Henrard, M. (2012b) Multi-Curves: Variations on a
Theme. Quantitative Research 6, OpenGamma. Available
from: http://docs.opengamma.com
Hunter, C. (2017) Introduction to Hybrid Modelling,
Oxford Financial Mathematics. University of Oxford,
Lecture notes, Advanced Modelling Topics 1
Musiela, M., and Rutkowski, M. (1997) Martingale
methods in financial modelling. Springer, First Edition
Musiela, M., and Rutkowski, M. (2005) Martingale
methods in financial modelling. Springer, Second Edition
Martìnez, T. (2009) Drift conditions on a HJM model with
stochastic basis spreads. Available from: http://www.risk
lab.es/es/jornadas/2009/index.html
Mercurio, F. (2009). Interest Rates and The Credit Crunch:
New Formulas and Market Models. Bloomberg Portfolio
Research Paper No. 2010-01-FRONTIERS. Available
from: http://ssrn.com/abstract=1332205
Morini, M. (2009). Solving the Puzzle in the Interest Rate
Market. Available from: http://ssrn.com/abstract=15060
46
Moreni, N., and Pallavicini, A. (2010) Parsimonious HJM
modelling for multiple yield-curve dynamics. Working
paper, SSRN. Available from: http://ssrn.com/abstract=16
99300
Mercurio, F. (2010) LIBOR Market Models with
Stochastic Basis. Available from: http://ssrn.com/abstract
=1563685
Mercurio, F., and Xie, Z. (2012) The basis goes stochastic.
Risk Magazine, pp. 78-83. Available from: https://www.ri
sk.net/media/download/929966
Shreve, S.E. (2004) Stochastic Calculus for Finance II:
Continuous-Time Models. Springer, First Edition
Theis, J. (2017) Modelling Interest Rate Derivatives.
University of Oxford, Lecture notes, Advanced Modelling
Topics 1
Vasicek, O. (1977) An equilibrium characterisation of the
term structure. Journal of Financial Economics, vol. 5, pp.
177-188

More Related Content

Similar to Multi-curve modelling

The Short-term Swap Rate Models in China
The Short-term Swap Rate Models in ChinaThe Short-term Swap Rate Models in China
Multifactorial Heath-Jarrow-Morton model using principal component analysis
Multifactorial Heath-Jarrow-Morton model using principal component analysisMultifactorial Heath-Jarrow-Morton model using principal component analysis
Multifactorial Heath-Jarrow-Morton model using principal component analysis
IJECEIAES
 
Vasicek Model Project
Vasicek Model ProjectVasicek Model Project
Vasicek Model Project
Cedric Melhy
 
Research on the Trading Strategy Based On Interest Rate Term Structure Change...
Research on the Trading Strategy Based On Interest Rate Term Structure Change...Research on the Trading Strategy Based On Interest Rate Term Structure Change...
Research on the Trading Strategy Based On Interest Rate Term Structure Change...
inventionjournals
 
PeterLoh_Dissertation
PeterLoh_DissertationPeterLoh_Dissertation
PeterLoh_Dissertation
Peter Loh JoonYoong
 
Advanced microeconometric project
Advanced microeconometric projectAdvanced microeconometric project
Advanced microeconometric project
LaurentCyrus
 
LPIs with a smile
LPIs with a smileLPIs with a smile
LPIs with a smile
CharvetXavier
 
Implimenting_HJM
Implimenting_HJMImplimenting_HJM
Implimenting_HJM
Abukar Ali, CQF
 
Matt Fagan MSM Analysis
Matt Fagan MSM AnalysisMatt Fagan MSM Analysis
Matt Fagan MSM Analysis
Matt Fagan
 
Combining Economic Fundamentals to Predict Exchange Rates
Combining Economic Fundamentals to Predict Exchange RatesCombining Economic Fundamentals to Predict Exchange Rates
Combining Economic Fundamentals to Predict Exchange Rates
Brant Munro
 
LFM Pedersen Calibration - Cappelli
LFM Pedersen Calibration - CappelliLFM Pedersen Calibration - Cappelli
LFM Pedersen Calibration - Cappelli
Joel Cappelli
 
Penalized Regressions with Different Tuning Parameter Choosing Criteria and t...
Penalized Regressions with Different Tuning Parameter Choosing Criteria and t...Penalized Regressions with Different Tuning Parameter Choosing Criteria and t...
Penalized Regressions with Different Tuning Parameter Choosing Criteria and t...
CSCJournals
 
Modelling of Commercial Banks Capitals Competition Dynamics
Modelling of Commercial Banks Capitals Competition DynamicsModelling of Commercial Banks Capitals Competition Dynamics
Modelling of Commercial Banks Capitals Competition Dynamics
Christo Ananth
 
Optimal combination of operators in Genetic Algorithmsfor VRP problems
Optimal combination of operators in Genetic Algorithmsfor VRP problemsOptimal combination of operators in Genetic Algorithmsfor VRP problems
Optimal combination of operators in Genetic Algorithmsfor VRP problems
International Journal of Modern Research in Engineering and Technology
 
Determinants of bank's interest margin in the aftermath of the crisis: the ef...
Determinants of bank's interest margin in the aftermath of the crisis: the ef...Determinants of bank's interest margin in the aftermath of the crisis: the ef...
Determinants of bank's interest margin in the aftermath of the crisis: the ef...
Ivie
 
opec_12048_Rev2
opec_12048_Rev2opec_12048_Rev2
opec_12048_Rev2
Per Bjarte Solibakke
 
Opec 12048 rev2
Opec 12048 rev2Opec 12048 rev2
Opec 12048 rev2
Per Bjarte Solibakke
 
ch2.pdf
ch2.pdfch2.pdf
ch2.pdf
OmarJawara
 
Forecasting Bitcoin Risk Measures: A Robust Approach
Forecasting Bitcoin Risk Measures: A Robust ApproachForecasting Bitcoin Risk Measures: A Robust Approach
Forecasting Bitcoin Risk Measures: A Robust Approach
Rafael Trucios Maza
 
Quantifying the Uncertainty of Long-Term Economic Projections
Quantifying the Uncertainty of Long-Term Economic ProjectionsQuantifying the Uncertainty of Long-Term Economic Projections
Quantifying the Uncertainty of Long-Term Economic Projections
Congressional Budget Office
 

Similar to Multi-curve modelling (20)

The Short-term Swap Rate Models in China
The Short-term Swap Rate Models in ChinaThe Short-term Swap Rate Models in China
The Short-term Swap Rate Models in China
 
Multifactorial Heath-Jarrow-Morton model using principal component analysis
Multifactorial Heath-Jarrow-Morton model using principal component analysisMultifactorial Heath-Jarrow-Morton model using principal component analysis
Multifactorial Heath-Jarrow-Morton model using principal component analysis
 
Vasicek Model Project
Vasicek Model ProjectVasicek Model Project
Vasicek Model Project
 
Research on the Trading Strategy Based On Interest Rate Term Structure Change...
Research on the Trading Strategy Based On Interest Rate Term Structure Change...Research on the Trading Strategy Based On Interest Rate Term Structure Change...
Research on the Trading Strategy Based On Interest Rate Term Structure Change...
 
PeterLoh_Dissertation
PeterLoh_DissertationPeterLoh_Dissertation
PeterLoh_Dissertation
 
Advanced microeconometric project
Advanced microeconometric projectAdvanced microeconometric project
Advanced microeconometric project
 
LPIs with a smile
LPIs with a smileLPIs with a smile
LPIs with a smile
 
Implimenting_HJM
Implimenting_HJMImplimenting_HJM
Implimenting_HJM
 
Matt Fagan MSM Analysis
Matt Fagan MSM AnalysisMatt Fagan MSM Analysis
Matt Fagan MSM Analysis
 
Combining Economic Fundamentals to Predict Exchange Rates
Combining Economic Fundamentals to Predict Exchange RatesCombining Economic Fundamentals to Predict Exchange Rates
Combining Economic Fundamentals to Predict Exchange Rates
 
LFM Pedersen Calibration - Cappelli
LFM Pedersen Calibration - CappelliLFM Pedersen Calibration - Cappelli
LFM Pedersen Calibration - Cappelli
 
Penalized Regressions with Different Tuning Parameter Choosing Criteria and t...
Penalized Regressions with Different Tuning Parameter Choosing Criteria and t...Penalized Regressions with Different Tuning Parameter Choosing Criteria and t...
Penalized Regressions with Different Tuning Parameter Choosing Criteria and t...
 
Modelling of Commercial Banks Capitals Competition Dynamics
Modelling of Commercial Banks Capitals Competition DynamicsModelling of Commercial Banks Capitals Competition Dynamics
Modelling of Commercial Banks Capitals Competition Dynamics
 
Optimal combination of operators in Genetic Algorithmsfor VRP problems
Optimal combination of operators in Genetic Algorithmsfor VRP problemsOptimal combination of operators in Genetic Algorithmsfor VRP problems
Optimal combination of operators in Genetic Algorithmsfor VRP problems
 
Determinants of bank's interest margin in the aftermath of the crisis: the ef...
Determinants of bank's interest margin in the aftermath of the crisis: the ef...Determinants of bank's interest margin in the aftermath of the crisis: the ef...
Determinants of bank's interest margin in the aftermath of the crisis: the ef...
 
opec_12048_Rev2
opec_12048_Rev2opec_12048_Rev2
opec_12048_Rev2
 
Opec 12048 rev2
Opec 12048 rev2Opec 12048 rev2
Opec 12048 rev2
 
ch2.pdf
ch2.pdfch2.pdf
ch2.pdf
 
Forecasting Bitcoin Risk Measures: A Robust Approach
Forecasting Bitcoin Risk Measures: A Robust ApproachForecasting Bitcoin Risk Measures: A Robust Approach
Forecasting Bitcoin Risk Measures: A Robust Approach
 
Quantifying the Uncertainty of Long-Term Economic Projections
Quantifying the Uncertainty of Long-Term Economic ProjectionsQuantifying the Uncertainty of Long-Term Economic Projections
Quantifying the Uncertainty of Long-Term Economic Projections
 

Recently uploaded

where can I find a legit pi merchant online
where can I find a legit pi merchant onlinewhere can I find a legit pi merchant online
where can I find a legit pi merchant online
DOT TECH
 
Who Is Abhay Bhutada, MD of Poonawalla Fincorp
Who Is Abhay Bhutada, MD of Poonawalla FincorpWho Is Abhay Bhutada, MD of Poonawalla Fincorp
Who Is Abhay Bhutada, MD of Poonawalla Fincorp
beulahfernandes8
 
2. Elemental Economics - Mineral demand.pdf
2. Elemental Economics - Mineral demand.pdf2. Elemental Economics - Mineral demand.pdf
2. Elemental Economics - Mineral demand.pdf
Neal Brewster
 
Pensions and housing - Pensions PlayPen - 4 June 2024 v3 (1).pdf
Pensions and housing - Pensions PlayPen - 4 June 2024 v3 (1).pdfPensions and housing - Pensions PlayPen - 4 June 2024 v3 (1).pdf
Pensions and housing - Pensions PlayPen - 4 June 2024 v3 (1).pdf
Henry Tapper
 
Independent Study - College of Wooster Research (2023-2024) FDI, Culture, Glo...
Independent Study - College of Wooster Research (2023-2024) FDI, Culture, Glo...Independent Study - College of Wooster Research (2023-2024) FDI, Culture, Glo...
Independent Study - College of Wooster Research (2023-2024) FDI, Culture, Glo...
AntoniaOwensDetwiler
 
Solution Manual For Financial Accounting, 8th Canadian Edition 2024, by Libby...
Solution Manual For Financial Accounting, 8th Canadian Edition 2024, by Libby...Solution Manual For Financial Accounting, 8th Canadian Edition 2024, by Libby...
Solution Manual For Financial Accounting, 8th Canadian Edition 2024, by Libby...
Donc Test
 
Tax System, Behaviour, Justice, and Voluntary Compliance Culture in Nigeria -...
Tax System, Behaviour, Justice, and Voluntary Compliance Culture in Nigeria -...Tax System, Behaviour, Justice, and Voluntary Compliance Culture in Nigeria -...
Tax System, Behaviour, Justice, and Voluntary Compliance Culture in Nigeria -...
Godwin Emmanuel Oyedokun MBA MSc PhD FCA FCTI FCNA CFE FFAR
 
Seminar: Gender Board Diversity through Ownership Networks
Seminar: Gender Board Diversity through Ownership NetworksSeminar: Gender Board Diversity through Ownership Networks
Seminar: Gender Board Diversity through Ownership Networks
GRAPE
 
when will pi network coin be available on crypto exchange.
when will pi network coin be available on crypto exchange.when will pi network coin be available on crypto exchange.
when will pi network coin be available on crypto exchange.
DOT TECH
 
一比一原版(UoB毕业证)伯明翰大学毕业证如何办理
一比一原版(UoB毕业证)伯明翰大学毕业证如何办理一比一原版(UoB毕业证)伯明翰大学毕业证如何办理
一比一原版(UoB毕业证)伯明翰大学毕业证如何办理
nexop1
 
BONKMILLON Unleashes Its Bonkers Potential on Solana.pdf
BONKMILLON Unleashes Its Bonkers Potential on Solana.pdfBONKMILLON Unleashes Its Bonkers Potential on Solana.pdf
BONKMILLON Unleashes Its Bonkers Potential on Solana.pdf
coingabbar
 
The Rise of Generative AI in Finance: Reshaping the Industry with Synthetic Data
The Rise of Generative AI in Finance: Reshaping the Industry with Synthetic DataThe Rise of Generative AI in Finance: Reshaping the Industry with Synthetic Data
The Rise of Generative AI in Finance: Reshaping the Industry with Synthetic Data
Champak Jhagmag
 
Independent Study - College of Wooster Research (2023-2024)
Independent Study - College of Wooster Research (2023-2024)Independent Study - College of Wooster Research (2023-2024)
Independent Study - College of Wooster Research (2023-2024)
AntoniaOwensDetwiler
 
WhatsPump Thriving in the Whirlwind of Biden’s Crypto Roller Coaster
WhatsPump Thriving in the Whirlwind of Biden’s Crypto Roller CoasterWhatsPump Thriving in the Whirlwind of Biden’s Crypto Roller Coaster
WhatsPump Thriving in the Whirlwind of Biden’s Crypto Roller Coaster
muslimdavidovich670
 
Abhay Bhutada Leads Poonawalla Fincorp To Record Low NPA And Unprecedented Gr...
Abhay Bhutada Leads Poonawalla Fincorp To Record Low NPA And Unprecedented Gr...Abhay Bhutada Leads Poonawalla Fincorp To Record Low NPA And Unprecedented Gr...
Abhay Bhutada Leads Poonawalla Fincorp To Record Low NPA And Unprecedented Gr...
Vighnesh Shashtri
 
Eco-Innovations and Firm Heterogeneity. Evidence from Italian Family and Nonf...
Eco-Innovations and Firm Heterogeneity.Evidence from Italian Family and Nonf...Eco-Innovations and Firm Heterogeneity.Evidence from Italian Family and Nonf...
Eco-Innovations and Firm Heterogeneity. Evidence from Italian Family and Nonf...
University of Calabria
 
DEMAND AND SUPPLY.docx Notes for Economics
DEMAND AND SUPPLY.docx Notes for EconomicsDEMAND AND SUPPLY.docx Notes for Economics
DEMAND AND SUPPLY.docx Notes for Economics
Opanga1
 
OAT_RI_Ep20 WeighingTheRisks_May24_Trade Wars.pptx
OAT_RI_Ep20 WeighingTheRisks_May24_Trade Wars.pptxOAT_RI_Ep20 WeighingTheRisks_May24_Trade Wars.pptx
OAT_RI_Ep20 WeighingTheRisks_May24_Trade Wars.pptx
hiddenlevers
 
SWAIAP Fraud Risk Mitigation Prof Oyedokun.pptx
SWAIAP Fraud Risk Mitigation   Prof Oyedokun.pptxSWAIAP Fraud Risk Mitigation   Prof Oyedokun.pptx
SWAIAP Fraud Risk Mitigation Prof Oyedokun.pptx
Godwin Emmanuel Oyedokun MBA MSc PhD FCA FCTI FCNA CFE FFAR
 
Role of Information Technology in Revenue - Prof Oyedokun.pptx
Role of Information Technology in Revenue  - Prof Oyedokun.pptxRole of Information Technology in Revenue  - Prof Oyedokun.pptx
Role of Information Technology in Revenue - Prof Oyedokun.pptx
Godwin Emmanuel Oyedokun MBA MSc PhD FCA FCTI FCNA CFE FFAR
 

Recently uploaded (20)

where can I find a legit pi merchant online
where can I find a legit pi merchant onlinewhere can I find a legit pi merchant online
where can I find a legit pi merchant online
 
Who Is Abhay Bhutada, MD of Poonawalla Fincorp
Who Is Abhay Bhutada, MD of Poonawalla FincorpWho Is Abhay Bhutada, MD of Poonawalla Fincorp
Who Is Abhay Bhutada, MD of Poonawalla Fincorp
 
2. Elemental Economics - Mineral demand.pdf
2. Elemental Economics - Mineral demand.pdf2. Elemental Economics - Mineral demand.pdf
2. Elemental Economics - Mineral demand.pdf
 
Pensions and housing - Pensions PlayPen - 4 June 2024 v3 (1).pdf
Pensions and housing - Pensions PlayPen - 4 June 2024 v3 (1).pdfPensions and housing - Pensions PlayPen - 4 June 2024 v3 (1).pdf
Pensions and housing - Pensions PlayPen - 4 June 2024 v3 (1).pdf
 
Independent Study - College of Wooster Research (2023-2024) FDI, Culture, Glo...
Independent Study - College of Wooster Research (2023-2024) FDI, Culture, Glo...Independent Study - College of Wooster Research (2023-2024) FDI, Culture, Glo...
Independent Study - College of Wooster Research (2023-2024) FDI, Culture, Glo...
 
Solution Manual For Financial Accounting, 8th Canadian Edition 2024, by Libby...
Solution Manual For Financial Accounting, 8th Canadian Edition 2024, by Libby...Solution Manual For Financial Accounting, 8th Canadian Edition 2024, by Libby...
Solution Manual For Financial Accounting, 8th Canadian Edition 2024, by Libby...
 
Tax System, Behaviour, Justice, and Voluntary Compliance Culture in Nigeria -...
Tax System, Behaviour, Justice, and Voluntary Compliance Culture in Nigeria -...Tax System, Behaviour, Justice, and Voluntary Compliance Culture in Nigeria -...
Tax System, Behaviour, Justice, and Voluntary Compliance Culture in Nigeria -...
 
Seminar: Gender Board Diversity through Ownership Networks
Seminar: Gender Board Diversity through Ownership NetworksSeminar: Gender Board Diversity through Ownership Networks
Seminar: Gender Board Diversity through Ownership Networks
 
when will pi network coin be available on crypto exchange.
when will pi network coin be available on crypto exchange.when will pi network coin be available on crypto exchange.
when will pi network coin be available on crypto exchange.
 
一比一原版(UoB毕业证)伯明翰大学毕业证如何办理
一比一原版(UoB毕业证)伯明翰大学毕业证如何办理一比一原版(UoB毕业证)伯明翰大学毕业证如何办理
一比一原版(UoB毕业证)伯明翰大学毕业证如何办理
 
BONKMILLON Unleashes Its Bonkers Potential on Solana.pdf
BONKMILLON Unleashes Its Bonkers Potential on Solana.pdfBONKMILLON Unleashes Its Bonkers Potential on Solana.pdf
BONKMILLON Unleashes Its Bonkers Potential on Solana.pdf
 
The Rise of Generative AI in Finance: Reshaping the Industry with Synthetic Data
The Rise of Generative AI in Finance: Reshaping the Industry with Synthetic DataThe Rise of Generative AI in Finance: Reshaping the Industry with Synthetic Data
The Rise of Generative AI in Finance: Reshaping the Industry with Synthetic Data
 
Independent Study - College of Wooster Research (2023-2024)
Independent Study - College of Wooster Research (2023-2024)Independent Study - College of Wooster Research (2023-2024)
Independent Study - College of Wooster Research (2023-2024)
 
WhatsPump Thriving in the Whirlwind of Biden’s Crypto Roller Coaster
WhatsPump Thriving in the Whirlwind of Biden’s Crypto Roller CoasterWhatsPump Thriving in the Whirlwind of Biden’s Crypto Roller Coaster
WhatsPump Thriving in the Whirlwind of Biden’s Crypto Roller Coaster
 
Abhay Bhutada Leads Poonawalla Fincorp To Record Low NPA And Unprecedented Gr...
Abhay Bhutada Leads Poonawalla Fincorp To Record Low NPA And Unprecedented Gr...Abhay Bhutada Leads Poonawalla Fincorp To Record Low NPA And Unprecedented Gr...
Abhay Bhutada Leads Poonawalla Fincorp To Record Low NPA And Unprecedented Gr...
 
Eco-Innovations and Firm Heterogeneity. Evidence from Italian Family and Nonf...
Eco-Innovations and Firm Heterogeneity.Evidence from Italian Family and Nonf...Eco-Innovations and Firm Heterogeneity.Evidence from Italian Family and Nonf...
Eco-Innovations and Firm Heterogeneity. Evidence from Italian Family and Nonf...
 
DEMAND AND SUPPLY.docx Notes for Economics
DEMAND AND SUPPLY.docx Notes for EconomicsDEMAND AND SUPPLY.docx Notes for Economics
DEMAND AND SUPPLY.docx Notes for Economics
 
OAT_RI_Ep20 WeighingTheRisks_May24_Trade Wars.pptx
OAT_RI_Ep20 WeighingTheRisks_May24_Trade Wars.pptxOAT_RI_Ep20 WeighingTheRisks_May24_Trade Wars.pptx
OAT_RI_Ep20 WeighingTheRisks_May24_Trade Wars.pptx
 
SWAIAP Fraud Risk Mitigation Prof Oyedokun.pptx
SWAIAP Fraud Risk Mitigation   Prof Oyedokun.pptxSWAIAP Fraud Risk Mitigation   Prof Oyedokun.pptx
SWAIAP Fraud Risk Mitigation Prof Oyedokun.pptx
 
Role of Information Technology in Revenue - Prof Oyedokun.pptx
Role of Information Technology in Revenue  - Prof Oyedokun.pptxRole of Information Technology in Revenue  - Prof Oyedokun.pptx
Role of Information Technology in Revenue - Prof Oyedokun.pptx
 

Multi-curve modelling

  • 1. Page 1 of 13 On HJM Model and Its Extension to Single-Currency-Multiple- Curves Modelling (Version 1 – 2017 Part I) Chong Seng Choi ARTICLE INFO ABSTRACT Keywords: Change-of-measure Convexity adjustment Credit crisis Cross-currency derivatives Discount curve FRAs Forward curve Libor rates No-arbitrage OIS rates Yield curve Classical interest-rate models are developed to incorporate no-arbitrage conditions, which allow one to hedge interest rate derivatives in terms of zero-coupon bonds. As a result, forward rates with different tenors are related to each other by sharp constraints, and these constraints between rates allowed the construction of a well- defined forward curve. However, after the credit crunch in August 2007, the Libor and OIS (risk-free) rates are separated by large basis spreads, which are no longer considered negligible. As a result, FRA rates can no longer be replicated by the spot Libor rates, and rates differing only for their payment frequency have started to show large inconsistencies. The present market situation has thus necessitated the development of single-currency-multiple-curves framework to take into account the divergences between rates. This paper aims at reviewing the classical HJM model and its extension to single-currency-multiple-curves valuation following a foreign- currency analogy. The valuation of FRA is examined and a convexity adjustment factor typical to the pricing of cross-currency derivatives is derived as a result. 1. Introduction Classical interest-rate models are developed to incorporate no-arbitrage conditions, which allow one to hedge interest rate derivatives in terms of zero-coupon bonds. As a result, forward rates with different tenors are related to each other by sharp constraints, and these constraints between rates allowed the construction of a well-defined forward curve. However, after the credit crunch in August 2007, a number of anomalies have emerged in that the market quotes of forward rates and zero-coupon bonds started to violate the no-arbitrage conditions embedded in these classical models. In the pre-crisis environment, the Libor and OIS (risk-free) rates were chasing each other closely, the spreads between swap rates with the same maturity but different payment lengths were negligible, and the market quotes of FRA had the precise relationship with the spot Libor rates that classical models predict. Therefore, the pre-crisis standard market practice was to construct only one unique yield curve and then compute on the same curve the discount and forward rates. Yet, in the post-crisis environment, the Libor and OIS rates are separated by large basis spreads, which are no longer considered negligible. As a result, FRA rates can no longer be replicated by the spot Libor rates, and rates differing only for their payment frequency have started to show large inconsistencies. For example, as noted by Mercurio (2009), a swap rate with semi-annual payments 1 For the rationale of choosing the HJM model, see Cuchiero, Fontana and Gnoatto (2014), and Theis (2017). based on the 6-month LIBOR can be different (and higher) than the same-maturity swap rate but with quarterly payments based on the 3-month LIBOR. These divergences between rates thus suggest that construction of a unique single yield curve for both discounting and forwarding is possible only in the absence of liquidity and counterparty risks. Indeed, the present market situation has necessitated the development of single-currency-multiple-curves framework to value interest rate derivatives in that a unique curve is built for discounting and separate curves corresponding to different rate tenors, i.e. 1M, 3M,6M and 12M, are constructed for forwarding. This paper aims at reviewing the classical HJM1 model and its extension to single-currency-multiple-curves valuation following the foreign-currency analogy put forward by Bianchetti (2009), Cuchiero, Fontana and Gnoatto (2014), and Theis (2017). The valuation of FRA is examined and a convexity adjustment typical to the pricing of cross-currency derivatives is derived as a result. Section 2 gives the mathematical notations used. Section 3 presents the derivations of the HJM model and Section 4 derives the dynamics of the forwarding curve under risk- neutral and forward probability measures. Section 5 briefly discusses the implementation and estimation procedure. Section 6 concludes.
  • 2.  On HJM Model and Its Extension to Single-Currency-Multiple-Curves Modelling Page 2 of 13 2. Mathematical Notation Assuming a continuous-time trading economy with trading interval [0, 𝑇∗ ] for a fixed horizon 𝑇∗ > 0. The uncertainty of the economy is defined on a probability space (Ω, 𝔽, ℙ) with filtration 𝔽, which is assumed to be the right-continuous and ℙ -completed version of the filtration generated by the underlying d-dimensional standard Brownian motion 𝑊. Further, assuming there exists a continuum of non- defaultable zero-coupon bonds with maturities 𝑇 ∈ [0, 𝑇∗], and let 𝐵(𝑡, 𝑇) denotes the price of the zero- coupon bond at time 𝑡 ≤ 𝑇, 𝑡 ∈ [0, 𝑇], maturing at time 𝑇 ≤ 𝑇∗ . The bond price 𝐵(𝑡, 𝑇) is a strictly positive real- valued adopted process with 𝐵(𝑇, 𝑇) = 1, and its partial derivative with respect to maturity T, 𝜕 𝑇 ln 𝐵(𝑡, 𝑇), exits for all 𝑇 ∈ [0, 𝑇∗ ] . Lastly, let 𝔼ℙ(∙) denotes the expectation under the probability measure ℙ. Let 𝐹(𝑡, 𝑇, 𝑇 + 𝛿) be the forward rates at time 𝑡 < 𝑇 for risk-free borrowing and lending at time 𝑇 maturing at time 𝑇 + 𝛿. Moreover, let 𝑓(𝑡, 𝑇) stands for the forward rate at time 𝑡 ≤ 𝑇 for instantaneous risk-free borrowing and lending at time 𝑇 ≤ 𝑇∗ . By taking the limit on 𝛿 𝑓(𝑡, 𝑇) = lim 𝛿→0 𝐹(𝑡, 𝑇, 𝑇 + 𝛿) = − lim 𝛿→0 1 𝐵(𝑡, 𝑇 + 𝛿) 𝐵(𝑡, 𝑇 + 𝛿) − 𝐵(𝑡, 𝑇) 𝛿 = − 1 𝐵(𝑡, 𝑇) 𝜕𝐵(𝑡, 𝑇) 𝜕𝑇 = − 𝜕 ln 𝐵(𝑡, 𝑇) 𝜕𝑇 (Brigo and Mercurio, 2006:p.12) The instantaneous forward rate 𝑓(𝑡, 𝑇) is thus given by 𝑓(𝑡, 𝑇) = − 𝜕 𝑇 ln 𝐵(𝑡, 𝑇) ∀ 𝑡 ∈ [0, 𝑇] (1) Integrating both sides and solving the above differential equation yields the following formula for zero bonds 𝐵(𝑡, 𝑇) = exp (− ∫ 𝑓(𝑡, 𝑠)𝑑𝑠 𝑇 𝑡 ) ∀ 𝑡 ∈ [0, 𝑇] (2) 3. The Classical HJM Model Previous interest rate models such as those of Vasicek (1977), Cox, Ingersoll, and Ross (1985), and Hull and White (1990) typically involved modelling directly the dynamics of the short rate 𝑟 since all fundamental quantities such as rates and bonds are readily defined, which facilitated a convenient specification. Further, the success of these models were mainly attributed to their analytical tractability and the availability of explicit 2 The Vasicek and the Hull-White models are two examples that produce negative rates with positive probability due to their assumptions of a Gaussian distribution. 3 The bond prices of most short-rate models such as those of Vasicek (1977), Dothan (1978), Cox, Ingersoll, and formulas for bonds and bond options (Brigo and Mercurio, 2006). Despite their advantages, these models generally come with a major drawback in that the initial term structure is endogenous rather than exogenous, meaning that the initial term structure is an output of these models. These endogenous term-structure models thus require users to run optimization to find the set of model parameters that fits as close as possible the initial curve to the market curve (Brigo and Mercurio, 2006). However, due to the small number of parameters in these short-rate models, it is often difficult to calibrate an accurate initial curve, and in some cases2 produce negative rates 𝑟𝑡 < 0. In-light of the major disadvantage of most short-rate models, one is thus in-need for a model that takes the initial term structure as exogenously given. The first such alternative was proposed by Ho and Lee (1986), who modelled the behaviour of the entire yield curve in a discrete setting instead of modelling the short-rate, which represented only a single point on this curve (Musiela and Rutkowski, 1997). Their intuition was then extended by Heath, Jarrow and Mortion (HJM) (1992) in a continuous time setting in that the instantaneous forward rates were chosen to be the fundamental quantities to model. The advantages of the HJM model lie not only in the exogenous term-structure but also in the fact that nearly all exogenous term-structure interest rate model can be derived within this general framework (Brigo and Mercurio, 2006). In particular, the HJM model links together the dynamics of forward rates and zero-coupon bond prices and assumes that the zero bonds evolve as a continuous stochastic process3 . Therefore, the HJM model is also a natural choice for single-currency-multiple- curves modelling. 3.1 HJM Forward-Rate Dynamics Heath, Jarrow and Morton (1992) assumes that for every fixed 𝑇 ≤ 𝑇∗ , the dynamics of the instantaneous forward rate satisfies the following stochastic process 𝑓(𝑡, 𝑇) = 𝑓(0, 𝑇) + ∫ 𝛼(𝑠, 𝑇)𝑑𝑠 + ∫ 𝜎(𝑠, 𝑇)𝑑𝑊(𝑠) 𝑡 0 𝑡 0 (3) for all 𝑡 ∈ [0, 𝑇], where 𝑓(0, 𝑇) = 𝑓 𝑀(0, 𝑇): [0, 𝑇∗] is the market instantaneous forward curve at time 𝑡 = 0, i.e. initial term structure. 𝑓(0,∙): [0, 𝑇∗ ] → ℝ is a Borel- measurable function and 𝛼 ∶ 𝐶 × Ω → ℝ and 𝜎 ∶ 𝐶 × Ω → ℝ 𝑑 are some functions such that 𝐶 = {(𝑠, 𝑡)|0 ≤ 𝑠 ≤ 𝑡 ≤ 𝑇∗}. Moreover, for any maturity T, 𝛼(∙, 𝑇) is an adopted process, and 𝜎(∙, 𝑇) = (𝜎1(∙, 𝑇), … , 𝜎 𝑑(∙, 𝑇)) is a vector of adopted processes such that Ross (1985), and Hull and White (1990) are derived by solving the time-t conditional expectation 𝐵(𝑡, 𝑇) = 𝔼 𝑡 {𝑒𝑥𝑝 (− ∫ 𝑟(𝑢)𝑑𝑢 𝑇 𝑡 )} and thus are no stochastic (see Brigo and Mercurio, 2006).
  • 3.  On HJM Model and Its Extension to Single-Currency-Multiple-Curves Modelling Page 3 of 13 ∫ |𝛼(𝑠, 𝑇)|𝑑𝑠 + ∫ ‖𝜎(𝑠, 𝑇)‖2 𝑑𝑠 < ∞, 𝑇 𝑡 ℙ 𝑇 𝑡 − 𝑎. 𝑠 (Musiela and Rutkowski, 1997) In this setup, the D-dimensional Brownian motion determines the stochastic dynamics of the entire forward rate term structure starting from the fixed initial term structure 𝑓 𝑀(0, 𝑇). 3.2 HJM Bond Price Dynamics For every fixed 𝑇 ≤ 𝑇∗ , assuming the dynamics of the bond price 𝐵(𝑡, 𝑇) are determined by the following expression 𝜕𝐵(𝑡, 𝑇) = 𝐵(𝑡, 𝑇)(𝑎(𝑡, 𝑇)𝑑𝑡 + 𝑏(𝑡, 𝑇)𝑑𝑊(𝑡)) (5) With the above HJM assumptions and equations (2) and (3), the discount bond process can be solved for in the following steps 𝐵(𝑡, 𝑇) = exp (− ∫ 𝑓(𝑡, 𝑠)𝑑𝑠 𝑇 𝑡 ) = exp ( − ( ∫ 𝑓(0, 𝑢)𝑑𝑢 + ∫ ∫ 𝛼(𝑠, 𝑢)𝑑𝑠𝑑𝑢 𝑡 0 𝑇 𝑡 𝑇 𝑡 + ∫ ∫ 𝜎(𝑠, 𝑢)𝑑𝑊(𝑠)𝑑𝑢 𝑡 0 𝑇 𝑡 )) By the Fubini’s standard and stochastic theorems, ∫ ∫ 𝛼(𝑠, 𝑢)𝑑𝑠𝑑𝑢 𝑡 0 𝑇 0 = ∫ ∫ 𝛼(𝑠, 𝑢)𝑑𝑢𝑑𝑠 𝑇 0 𝑡 0 = ∫ ∫ 𝛼(𝑠, 𝑢)𝑑𝑢𝑑𝑠 + ∫ ∫ 𝛼(𝑠, 𝑢)𝑑𝑢𝑑𝑠 𝑡 𝑠 𝑡 0 𝑇 𝑠 𝑡 0 = ∫ ∫ 𝛼(𝑢, 𝑠)𝑑𝑠𝑑𝑢 + ∫ ∫ 𝛼(𝑠, 𝑢)𝑑𝑠𝑑𝑢 𝑢 0 𝑡 0 𝑇 𝑢 𝑡 0 and the same holds for ∬ 𝜎(𝑠, 𝑢)𝑑𝑊𝑠 𝑑𝑢, ∫ ∫ 𝜎(𝑠, 𝑢)𝑑𝑊𝑠 𝑑𝑢 𝑡 0 𝑇 0 = ∫ ∫ 𝜎(𝑠, 𝑢)𝑑𝑢𝑑𝑊(𝑠) 𝑇 0 𝑡 0 = ∫ ∫ 𝜎(𝑠, 𝑢)𝑑𝑢𝑑𝑊𝑠 + ∫ ∫ 𝜎(𝑠, 𝑢)𝑑𝑢𝑑𝑊(𝑠) 𝑡 𝑠 𝑡 0 𝑇 𝑠 𝑡 0 = ∫ ∫ 𝜎(𝑢, 𝑠)𝑑𝑠𝑑𝑊𝑢 + ∫ ∫ 𝜎(𝑠, 𝑢)𝑑𝑢𝑑𝑊(𝑠) 𝑢 0 𝑡 0 𝑇 𝑢 𝑡 0 we thus have 𝐵(𝑡, 𝑇) = exp ( − ∫ 𝑓(0, 𝑢)𝑑𝑢 − ∫ ∫ 𝛼(𝑢, 𝑠)𝑑𝑠𝑑𝑢 𝑇 𝑢 𝑡 0 𝑇 0 – ∫ ∫ 𝜎(𝑢, 𝑠)𝑑𝑠𝑑𝑊(𝑢) 𝑇 𝑢 𝑡 0 + ∫ (𝑓(0, 𝑢) + ∫ 𝛼(𝑠, 𝑢)𝑑𝑠 𝑢 0 + ∫ 𝜎(𝑠, 𝑢)𝑑𝑊(𝑠) 𝑢 0 ) ⏟ 𝑑𝑢 𝑡 0 𝑓(𝑢, 𝑢) ) (6) Moreover, the short rate 𝑟𝑢 at time 𝑢 can be derived using the forward rate equation and taking the limit on 𝛿 over the time interval [𝑢, 𝑢 + 𝛿] 𝑟𝑢 = 𝑓(𝑢, 𝑢) = lim 𝛿→0 [𝛿−1 ( 1 − 𝐵(𝑢, 𝑢 + 𝛿) 𝐵(𝑢, 𝑢 + 𝛿) )] = 𝑓(0, 𝑢) + ∫ 𝛼(𝑠, 𝑢)𝑑𝑠 𝑢 0 + ∫ 𝜎(𝑠, 𝑢)𝑑𝑊(𝑠) 𝑢 0 (7) (Heath, Jarrow and Morton, 1992) Writing equation (6) in the form of an 𝐼𝑡𝑜̃ process, we have 𝐵(𝑡, 𝑇) = 𝐵(0, 𝑇) 𝑒𝑥𝑝 (∫ 𝑟𝑢 𝑑𝑢 − ∫ ⋀(𝑢, 𝑇)𝑑𝑢 + ∫ Σ(𝑢, 𝑇)𝑑𝑊(𝑢) 𝑡 0 𝑡 0 𝑡 0 ) (8) where 𝐵(0, 𝑇) = exp (− ∫ 𝑓(0, 𝑢)𝑑𝑢 𝑇 0 ) ⋀(𝑢, 𝑇) = ∫ 𝛼(𝑡, 𝑠)𝑑𝑠, 𝑇 𝑡 Σ(𝑢, 𝑇) = ∫ 𝜎(𝑡, 𝑠)𝑑𝑠 𝑇 𝑡 The coefficients in equation (5) can be derived using equation (8) and the 𝐼𝑡𝑜̃ formula to solve for 𝐵(𝑡, 𝑇) = ln(𝐵(𝑡, 𝑇)). In differential form, equation (8) equals 𝜕𝐵(𝑡, 𝑇) = 𝐵(𝑡, 𝑇)[(𝑟𝑡 − ⋀(𝑡, 𝑇)𝑑𝑡 + Σ(𝑡, 𝑇)𝑑𝑊(𝑡)] and by the 𝐼𝑡𝑜̃ formula, 𝜕𝐵(𝑡, 𝑇) 𝐵(𝑡, 𝑇) = 𝜕𝐵(𝑡, 𝑇) + 1 2 [𝜕𝐵(𝑡, 𝑇)]2 = (𝑟𝑡 − ⋀(𝑡, 𝑇) + 1 2 |Σ(𝑡, 𝑇)|2 ) 𝑑𝑡 − Σ(𝑡, 𝑇)𝑑𝑊(𝑡) (9) Thus, we have 𝑎(𝑡, 𝑇) = 𝑟𝑡 − ⋀(𝑡, 𝑇) + 1 2 |Σ(𝑡, 𝑇)|2 and, 𝑏(𝑡, 𝑇) = − Σ(𝑡, 𝑇) 3.3 No-Arbitrage Condition In the HJM setting, a continuum of bonds with different maturities, 0 < 𝑇1 < 𝑇2 < ⋯ < 𝑇 𝑘 ≤ 𝑇∗ , is available for trade, therefore, one must ensure that there is no opportunity for arbitrage by trading bonds with different maturities. From The First Fundamental Theorem of Asset Pricing, the bond price process 𝐵(𝑡, 𝑇), 𝑡 ≤ 𝑇 ≤ 𝑇∗ , is arbitrage
  • 4.  On HJM Model and Its Extension to Single-Currency-Multiple-Curves Modelling Page 4 of 13 free if and only if there exits a probability measure ℙ̃ on (Ω, 𝔽 𝑇∗̃) that is equivalent to ℙ such that for any maturity 𝑇 ∈ [0, 𝑇∗], the discounted bond price 𝐵(𝑡,𝑇) 𝐵𝑡 is a martingale under ℙ̃. Let us first introduce the saving account 𝐵𝑡, which is also an adapted process defined on a filtered probability space (Ω, 𝔽, ℙ). 𝐵𝑡 is the amount of cash accumulated up to time 𝑡 by rolling over a risk-free bond and starting with one unit of cash at time 0. Thus, the process for 𝐵𝑡 is given by 𝐵𝑡 = exp (∫ 𝑓(𝑢, 𝑢)𝑑𝑢 𝑡 0 ) ∀ 𝑡 ∈ [0, 𝑇∗ ] (10) where 𝐵0 = 1, 0 < 𝐵𝑡 < +∞ By the 𝐼𝑡𝑜̃ quotient rule 𝜕(𝐵(𝑡, 𝑇)/𝐵𝑡) 𝐵(𝑡, 𝑇)/𝐵𝑡 = 𝜕𝐵(𝑡, 𝑇) 𝐵(𝑡, 𝑇) − 𝜕𝐵𝑡 𝐵𝑡 + 𝜕[𝐵𝑡, 𝐵𝑡] 𝐵𝑡 2 − 𝜕[𝐵(𝑡, 𝑇), 𝐵𝑡] 𝐵(𝑡, 𝑇)𝐵𝑡 = (𝑟𝑡 − ⋀(𝑡, 𝑇) + 1 2 |Σ(𝑡, 𝑇)|2 ) 𝑑𝑡 − Σ(𝑡, 𝑇)𝑑𝑊(𝑡) − 𝑟𝑡 𝑑𝑡 = (−⋀(𝑡, 𝑇) + 1 2 |Σ(𝑡, 𝑇)|2 ) 𝑑𝑡 − Σ(𝑡, 𝑇)𝑑𝑊(𝑡) (11) where 𝜕𝐵𝑡 = 𝐵𝑡 𝑟𝑡 𝑑𝑡 (12) From the above conditions, there must exist a probability measure measure ℙ̃ on (Ω, 𝔽 𝑇∗̃ ) equivalent to ℙ in order to ensure that there is no opportunity for arbitrage. In a financial interpretation, the underlying probability measure ℙ represents actual probability, which is a subjective assessment of the future evolution of the discounted bond price and therefore is not a martingale under ℙ. On the other hand, the probability measure ℙ̃ reflects risk-neutral probability, which renders the discounted bond price a martingale under ℙ̃ with zero drift. Defining 𝑍(𝑡, 𝑇) = 𝐵(𝑡,𝑇) 𝐵𝑡 and rearranging the terms in (11), we have 𝜕𝑍(𝑡, 𝑇) 𝑍(𝑡, 𝑇) = − Σ(𝑡, 𝑇)[𝜃𝑡 𝑑𝑡 + 𝑑𝑊(𝑡)] (13) where 𝜃𝑡 = −⋀(𝑡, 𝑇) + 1 2 |Σ(𝑡, 𝑇)|2 − Σ(𝑡, 𝑇) (14) is the market price of risk under the probability measure ℙ. We can then proceed to define a new probability measure ℙ̃ equivalent to ℙ on (Ω, 𝔽 𝑇∗̃ ) using the 𝑅𝑎𝑑𝑜𝑛 -𝑁𝑖𝑘𝑜𝑑𝑦́ 𝑚 𝑑𝑒𝑟𝑖𝑣𝑎𝑡𝑖𝑣𝑒 𝜕ℙ̃ 𝜕ℙ = ℇ 𝑇∗ (∫ 𝜃𝑡 ∙ 0 𝑑𝑊𝑡) ℙ − 𝑎. 𝑠. for some predictable ℝ 𝑑 -valued process adopted to the filtration 𝔽 𝑊 . The notation ℇ(∙) is the 𝐷𝑜𝑙𝑒́ 𝑎 𝑛𝑠 𝑒𝑥𝑝𝑜𝑛𝑒𝑛𝑡𝑖𝑎𝑙, which gives ℇ 𝑇∗ (∫ 𝜃𝑡 ∙ 0 𝑑𝑊𝑡) = 𝑒𝑥𝑝 (∫ 𝜃 𝑢 𝑡 0 𝑑𝑊(𝑢) − 1 2 ∫ |𝜃 𝑢|2 𝑡 0 𝑑𝑊(𝑢)) In view of Girsanov’s Theorem, the process 𝑊̃ (𝑡) = 𝑊(𝑡) + ∫ 𝜃 𝑢 𝑡 0 𝑑𝑢 ∀ 𝑡 ∈ [0, 𝑇∗ ] (15) follows a d-dimensional Brownian motion under ℙ̃. Thus we can change the probability measure of 𝑍(𝑡, 𝑇) from ℙ to ℙ̃ 𝜕𝑍(𝑡, 𝑇) 𝑍(𝑡, 𝑇) = − Σ(𝑡, 𝑇)[𝜃𝑡 𝑑𝑡 + (𝑑𝑊̃ (𝑡) − 𝜃𝑡 𝑑𝑡)] = − Σ(𝑡, 𝑇) 𝑑𝑊̃ (𝑡) (16) which is a martingale under ℙ̃. Since equation (11) and (13) are equivalent, we can then derive 𝛼(𝑡, 𝑇) in the forward process (3), under the measure ℙ, by solving the following equation (−⋀(𝑡, 𝑇) + 1 2 |Σ(𝑡, 𝑇)|2 ) 𝑑𝑡 − Σ(𝑡, 𝑇)𝑑𝑊(𝑡) = − Σ(𝑡, 𝑇)[𝜃𝑡 𝑑𝑡 + 𝑑𝑊(𝑡)] −⋀(𝑡, 𝑇) + 1 2 |Σ(𝑡, 𝑇)|2 = − Σ(𝑡, 𝑇)𝜃𝑡 (17) and by differentiating the equation with respect to T 𝜕 𝑇 [−⋀(𝑡, 𝑇) + 1 2 |Σ(𝑡, 𝑇)|2 ] = 𝜕 𝑇[− Σ(𝑡, 𝑇)𝜃𝑡] −𝛼(𝑡, 𝑇) + Σ(𝑡, 𝑇)𝜎(𝑡, 𝑇) = 𝜎(𝑡, 𝑇)𝜃𝑡 𝛼(𝑡, 𝑇) = 𝜎(𝑡, 𝑇)[Σ(𝑡, 𝑇) + 𝜃𝑡] (18) Thus, under the actual measure ℙ, we have 𝜕𝑓(𝑡, 𝑇) 𝑓(𝑡, 𝑇) = (𝜎(𝑡, 𝑇)Σ(𝑡, 𝑇) + 𝜎(𝑡, 𝑇)𝜃𝑡)𝑑𝑡 + 𝜎(𝑡, 𝑇)𝑑𝑊(𝑡) (19) 𝜕𝐵(𝑡, 𝑇) 𝐵(𝑡, 𝑇) = (𝑟𝑡 − Σ(𝑡, 𝑇)𝜃𝑡)𝑑𝑡 − Σ(𝑡, 𝑇)𝑑𝑊(𝑡) (20)
  • 5.  On HJM Model and Its Extension to Single-Currency-Multiple-Curves Modelling Page 5 of 13 𝜕𝑍(𝑡, 𝑇) 𝑍(𝑡, 𝑇) = − Σ(𝑡, 𝑇)[𝜃𝑡 𝑑𝑡 + 𝑑𝑊(𝑡)] (21) If a term-structure model satisfies the HJM no-arbitrage conditions then under the risk-neutral probability measure ℙ̃ and by Girsanov’s Theorem in (15), we have 𝜕𝑓(𝑡, 𝑇) 𝑓(𝑡, 𝑇) = 𝜎(𝑡, 𝑇)Σ(𝑡, 𝑇)𝑑𝑡 + 𝜎(𝑡, 𝑇)𝑑𝑊̃ (𝑡) (22) and the zero-coupon bond prices 𝜕𝐵(𝑡, 𝑇) 𝐵(𝑡, 𝑇) = 𝑟𝑡 𝑑𝑡 − Σ(𝑡, 𝑇)𝑑𝑊̃ (𝑡) (23) and the discounted bond prices 𝜕𝑍(𝑡, 𝑇) 𝑍(𝑡, 𝑇) = − Σ(𝑡, 𝑇) 𝑑𝑊̃ (𝑡) (24) Equations (19) - (24) are intuitive in that, under the risk- neutral expectation, the bond price satisfies 𝐵(𝑡, 𝑇) = 𝐵𝑡 𝔼 𝑡 ℙ̃ (𝐵 𝑇 −1 |ℱ𝑡) = 𝔼 𝑡 ℙ̃ (𝑒𝑥𝑝 (− ∫ 𝑓(𝑢, 𝑢)𝑑𝑢 𝑇 𝑡 )| ℱ𝑡) Consequently, given any non-negative forward rate process 𝑓 defined on a probability space (Ω, 𝔽, ℙ) and a probability measure ℙ̃ on (Ω, 𝔽 𝑇∗̃) equivalent to ℙ, the market price of risk 𝜃 must vanish under the risk-neutral measure ℙ̃. The HJM no-arbitrage conditions are best summarized as follow I. For any collection of maturities 0 < 𝑇1 < 𝑇2 < ⋯ < 𝑇 𝑘 ≤ 𝑇∗ , there exit market prices of risk 𝜃 𝑖(∙ ; 𝒯) such that −⋀𝑖(∙, 𝒯) + 1 2 |Σ 𝑖(∙, 𝒯)| 2 + Σ 𝑖(∙, 𝒯)𝜃 𝑖(∙ ; 𝒯) = 0 which satisfies ∫ |𝜃 𝑖(𝑢 ; 𝒯)| 2 𝑇 𝑖 0 𝑑𝑢 < +∞ 𝑓𝑜𝑟 𝑖 = 1, … , 𝑘 and 𝔼ℙ (ℇ 𝑇∗ (∫ 𝜃 𝑖(𝑢 ; 𝒯) ∙ 0 𝑑𝑊 𝑖 (𝑢))) = 1 and 4 In a FRA contact, a fixed payment based on the strike K, set at time 𝑡, is exchanged against a floating payment at 𝔼ℙ (ℇ 𝑇∗ (∫ (Σ 𝑖(𝑢, 𝒯) + 𝜃 𝑖(𝑢 ; 𝒯)) ∙ 0 𝑑𝑊 𝑖 (𝑢))) = 1 for 𝒯 ∈ [𝑇1 , … , 𝑇 𝑘 ] and 𝑖 = 1, … , 𝑘 II. There exits a probability measure ℙ̃ equivalent to ℙ such that for any collection of maturities 0 < 𝑇1 < 𝑇2 < ⋯ < 𝑇 𝑘 ≤ 𝑇∗ the discounted bond prices 𝑍(∙, 𝒯) are martingales under ℙ̃ with respect to 𝑓(∙, 𝒯). III. The martingale measures in (II) are unique across all bonds of all maturities 0 < 𝑇1 < 𝑇2 < ⋯ < 𝑇 𝑘 ≤ 𝑇∗ where  ℙ̃ is defined as ℙ̃ 𝑇1,…,𝑇 𝑘 for any maturity 0 < 𝑇1 < ⋯ < 𝑇 𝑘 ≤ 𝑇∗ and ℙ̃ 𝑇 𝑖 is the unique equivalent probability measure such that 𝑍(𝑡, 𝑇) is a martingale for all 𝑇 ∈ [0, 𝑇∗ ] and 𝑡 ∈ [0, 𝑇 𝑖 ]  𝛼(𝑡, 𝑇) = ∑ 𝜎 𝑖(𝑡, 𝑇) [∫ 𝜎 𝑖(𝑡, 𝑢)𝑑𝑢 𝑇 𝑡 + 𝜃 𝑖(∙𝑘 𝑖=1 ; 𝒯)] for all 𝑇 ∈ [0, 𝑇∗ ], 𝑡 ∈ [0, 𝑇] and for any 𝒯 ∈ (0, 𝑇∗ ], Arbitrage-free bond pricing and term structure movements (Heath, Jarrow and Merton, 1992:p. 83-87) 4. Post Liquidity Crisis The direct result of the no-arbitrage conditions embedded in HJM model and in other interest rate models is that they link together the forward rates and zero-coupon bonds, and thus allow one to price and hedge interest rate derivatives on any single currency. In fixed income markets, the underlying quantities of majority of interest-rate sensitive products are the Libor rates 𝐿(𝑡, 𝑇, 𝑇 + 𝛿), where 𝛿 > 0 corresponds to the underlying rate tenors 1D, 1M, 3M, 6M, and 12M. In the classical setting, the Libor rates are associated with the forward rates 𝐹 under a forward probability measure, namely 𝔼 𝑡 ℙ̃ 𝑇+𝛿 (𝐿(𝑇, 𝑇, 𝑇 + 𝛿)|ℱ𝑡) ≔ 𝐹(𝑡, 𝑇, 𝑇 + 𝛿) (25) and therefore the Libor rates can be replicated by buying and selling zero bonds with maturities corresponding those of the Libor rates, namely 𝐹(𝑡, 𝑇, 𝑇 + 𝛿) ≔ 𝛿−1 ( 𝐵(𝑡, 𝑇) 𝐵(𝑡, 𝑇 + 𝛿) − 1) (26) where 𝛿 is the year fraction between times 𝑇 and 𝑇 + 𝛿. In this sense, the discounted bonds 𝐵(𝑡, 𝑇) and the forward rates 𝐹(𝑡, 𝑇, 𝑇 + 𝛿) are computed using the spot Libor quotes prevailing in the market at time 𝑡, 𝐿 𝑀 (𝑡, 𝑇). Taking as example the pricing of FRA 4 (Forward Rate maturity, 𝑇 + 𝛿, based on the spot Libor rate at time at maturity 𝑇 for period [𝑇, 𝑇 + 𝛿].
  • 6.  On HJM Model and Its Extension to Single-Currency-Multiple-Curves Modelling Page 6 of 13 Agreement), the valuation of such contract, assuming a $1 notional, is given by FRA (𝑡, 𝑇, 𝑇 + 𝛿, 𝐾) = 𝐵(𝑡, 𝑇 + 𝛿)𝛿(𝐾 − 𝐿(𝑡, 𝑇, 𝑇 + 𝛿)) (Brigo and Mercurio, 2006) where 𝐾 is the strike that renders the contract fair at initiation time 𝑡. Thus we have the time 𝑡 price of a FRA equals to the strike 𝐾, giving 𝐾 = 𝔼 𝑡 ℙ̃ 𝑇+𝛿 (𝐿(𝑇, 𝑇, 𝑇 + 𝛿)|ℱ𝑡) = 𝛿−1 ( 𝐵(𝑡, 𝑇) 𝐵(𝑡, 𝑇 + 𝛿) − 1) (27) In this setting, Libor is not only the rate to which the FRA is referenced but also the rate used to discount future cash-flows. It is thus assumed that the risk in the interbank lending market is negligible, and Libor rates can be considered risk-free. As stressed by Bianchetti (2009), this setting is known as single-currency-single-curve approach in that a unique yield curve is constructed and used to price and hedge interest rate derivatives on a given currency. Before the crisis in 2007, the OIS5 , commonly used as the risk-free rate, and Libor rates were closely tracking each other, and the market quotes of FRA rates had a precise relationship with the spot Libor rates that the FRAs are indexed to, i.e. equation (27). Yet, after the financial crisis in 2007-2008 and the Eurozone sovereign debt crisis in 2009-2012, the classical assumptions do not hold anymore, with the basis spreads between the OIS and Libor rates now larger than those in the past and are no longer considered negligible. The main reasons behind this phenomenon can be attributed to counterparty risk, the risk of the counterparty defaulting on the contract obligation, and liquidity risk, the risk of excessive funding cost to finance the contract due to the lack of liquidity in the market. Unfortunately, the increase in the basis spreads does not create any arbitrage opportunities when counterparty and liquidity risks are taken into account (Mercurio, 2009). Therefore, the FRA rates can no longer be replicated by the spot Libor rates, and the floating legs differing only for the tenor 𝛿 are now represented by large basis spreads Morini (2009). Indeed, with the counterparty and liquidity risk in mind, Libor rates are not longer considered risk-free and the OIS rates are now a more appropriate candidate for discounting future cash-flows. The market has thus evolved to a single-currency- multiple-curves approach to take into account the different dynamics represented by Libor rates with different tenors and the discount rates that should be represented by a unique separate discounting curve. From Ametrano and Bianchetti (2013) Section 2.2, the corresponding approach can be summarized as follows:  Build a unique discounting curve using the OIS rates 5 According to Morini (2009), ‘an OIS, Overnight Index Swap, is a fixed/floating interest rate swap with the floating leg tied to a published index of a daily overnight  Build multiple forwarding curves for the Libor rates associated with difference tenors 𝛿  Use the market quotes of multiple separated sets of vanilla interest rate instruments with increasing maturity to bootstrap the forwarding curves  Compute on the forwarding curves the forward rates  Compute on the discounting curve the discount rates Post-crisis procedure for constructing multiple yield curves (Ametrano and Bianchetti, 2013:p.7) Returning to the FRA pricing equation, we know that equation (27) does not hold anymore 𝔼 𝑡 ℙ̃ 𝑇+𝛿 (𝐿(𝑇, 𝑇, 𝑇 + 𝛿)|ℱ𝑡) ≠ 𝛿−1 ( 𝐵(𝑡, 𝑇) 𝐵(𝑡, 𝑇 + 𝛿) − 1) because now 𝐿(𝑡, 𝑇, 𝑇 + 𝛿) > 𝐹(𝑡, 𝑇, 𝑇 + 𝛿). Adopting the multi-curves approach and the framework noted above, we have the floating leg of the FRA given by 𝑭𝑹𝑨 𝒇𝒍𝒐𝒂𝒕𝒊𝒏𝒈 (𝑡, 𝑇, 𝑇 + 𝛿) = 𝛿𝐵 𝑑(𝑡, 𝑇 + 𝛿) [𝛿−1 ( 𝐵 𝑓(𝑡, 𝑇) 𝐵 𝑓(𝑡, 𝑇 + 𝛿) − 1)] = 𝛿𝐵 𝑑(𝑡, 𝑇 + 𝛿)[𝐹𝑓(𝑡, 𝑇, 𝑇 + 𝛿)] (28) where 𝐵 𝑑(𝑡, ∙ ) is the discount factors computed from the discounting curve and 𝐵 𝑓(𝑡, ∙ ) is the zero bond prices computed from the forwarding curves. Using the martingale property of forward rates, we therefore need to compute equation (28) with the following expectation 𝔼 𝑡 ℙ̃ 𝑑 𝑇+𝛿 (𝐿(𝑇, 𝑇, 𝑇 + 𝛿)|ℱ𝑡) = 𝔼 𝑡 ℙ̃ 𝑑 𝑇+𝛿 (𝐹𝑓(𝑇, 𝑇, 𝑇 + 𝛿)) (29) where 𝔼 𝑡 ℙ̃ 𝑑 𝑇+𝛿 is the expectation at time 𝑡 under the discounting - 𝑇 + 𝛿 - forward neutral probability measure ℙ̃ 𝑑 𝑇+𝛿 . 4.1 Multi-Curves Modelling The single currency multi-curves modelling framework was first proposed by Henrard (2007) who describes a market in which each forward rate seems to act as a separate underlying asset. Subsequently, other authors have proposed several ways to go beyond the deterministic basis spread assumption. Martinez (2009) derives the drift conditions on a HJM model in the presence of a stochastic basis but focuses only on risk-neutral measure. Mercurio and Xie (2012) and Cuchiero, Fontana and Gnoatto (2014) model the Libor-OIS spread directly as a stochastic process. While Cuchiero, Fontana and Gnoatto (2014) generalize the HJM model, Mercurio (2010) extends the Libor reference rate. Since an overnight rate refers to lending for an extremely short period of time, it is assumed to incorporate negligible credit or liquidity risk.’ (p.10)
  • 7.  On HJM Model and Its Extension to Single-Currency-Multiple-Curves Modelling Page 7 of 13 Market Model to incorporate an additive stochastic basis. Moreover, OpenGamma (2012b) extends the Gaussian HJM model to a multi-curves framework with deterministic spread. Moreni and Pallavicini (2010) use a HJM-LMM hybrid model in which the discounting curve is described by a HJM dynamic while the forwarding curves are modelled through a Libor Market approach. In particular, Bianchetti (2009) and Theis (2017) recognizes an analogy between FX pricing and the pricing of interest rate derivatives when discounting is decoupled by indexing (Morini, 2009), leading to a convexity adjustment in the pricing equation. In light of the simplicity of the foreign-currency analogy examined by Bianchetti (2009) and Theis (2017), we shall follow their approach and apply it to the HJM model. The resulting single-currency-double-curves framework can be easily extended to a multi-curves setting. 4.2 Foreign-Currency Analogy Let us first consider the rationale behind this modelling choice. As in Bianchetti (2009), and Cuchiero, Fontana and Gnoatto (2014), one can associate the risky Libor rate with artificial risky bonds 𝐵 𝑓(𝑡, 𝑇) issued by a bank representative of the Libor panel. In this case, the pricing procedure is consistent with the classical risk-free setting, namely, 1+ 𝛿𝐿(𝑇, 𝑇, 𝑇 + 𝛿) = 1 𝐵 𝑓(𝑇,𝑇,𝑇+𝛿) . Moreover, if we interpret the risk-free bonds as domestic assets while the artificial bonds as foreign assets expressed in unit of foreign currency, we can introduce a spot “exchange” rate 𝑆𝑡, which allows us to link together the risk-free and the artificial risky bonds. Applying this foreign-currency analogy, we can proceed to derive a forward “exchange” rate 𝐹𝑆(𝑡, 𝑇, 𝑇 + 𝛿) over the period [𝑡, 𝑇] for settlement date 𝑇 + 𝛿 under the standard no-arbitrage argument in the foreign exchange markets. Naturally, the quantity 𝐹𝑆(𝑡, 𝑇, 𝑇 + 𝛿) can be interpreted as a multiplicative forward interest rate spread between the risk-free and risky bonds over the period [𝑇, 𝑇 + 𝛿]. As we shall see, different interpretations of the quantity 𝐹𝑆(𝑡, 𝑇, 𝑇 + 𝛿) would give different results for the single-currency- double-curves framework. Nonetheless, in-light of the above discussion, the foreign-currency analogy remains a natural modelling choice. Conversely, as in Theis (2017), we can consider 𝑆𝑡 6 the price at time 𝑡 of a unit of currency borrowed on a rolling basis at the risk-free rate and invested in the risky rate starting from time 0. In this sense, the foreign-currency analogy allows one to absorb the credit risk through the exchange rate 𝑆𝑡 and therefore treating the artificial risky bond process as continuous and continuously evolving consistent with standard interest rate modelling practice. Nevertheless, let us consider the framework of Bianchetti (2009) and assume that there exit two different interest markets 𝑀 𝑥 with 𝑥 = {𝑑, 𝑓} denoting respectively the domestic (discounting) and foreign (forwarding) market. Moreover, there are also two distinct 6 In Theis (2017), the quantity 𝑆𝑡 models the cumulative credit risk of an investment in the risky bonds, and it is saving accounts 𝐵𝑡 𝑥 , thus in the HJM setting we have the following dynamics under the 𝑥 - risk-neutral measure 𝜕𝑓 𝑥(𝑡, 𝑇) 𝑓 𝑥(𝑡, 𝑇) = 𝜎 𝑥(𝑡, 𝑇)Σ 𝑥(𝑡, 𝑇)𝑑𝑡 + 𝜎 𝑥(𝑡, 𝑇)𝑑𝑊̃𝑥(𝑡) (30) 𝜕𝐵 𝑥(𝑡, 𝑇) 𝐵 𝑥(𝑡, 𝑇) = 𝑟𝑡 𝑥 𝑑𝑡 − Σ 𝑥(𝑡, 𝑇)𝑑𝑊̃𝑥(𝑡) (31) 𝜕𝐵𝑡 𝑥 𝐵𝑡 𝑥 = 𝑟𝑡 𝑥 𝑑𝑡 (32) Moreover, a tradable asset in a foreign currency 𝑓 is tradable in the domestic market through the exchange rate 𝑆. Thus, if 𝑋 𝑓 is the price process of the foreign asset, 𝑋𝑡 𝑓 𝑆𝑡 will be the price process of the foreign asset in domestic currency. From Theis (2017), there must exist a pre-visible process 𝜎𝑡 𝑠 such that the exchange rate process can be postulated as follow 𝜕𝑆𝑡 𝑆𝑡 = (𝜇 𝑡 𝑑𝑡 + 𝜎𝑡 𝑠 𝑑𝑊̃ 𝑆(𝑡)) (33) where the process 𝑆𝑡 is defined on a filtered probability space (Ω, 𝔽, ℙ) with the filtration 𝔽 assumed to be the ℙ- augmentation of the filtration generated by a d- dimensional Brownian motion and ∫ |𝜎 𝑢 𝑠|2 𝑑𝑢 < 𝑡 0 ∞. Putting aside the foreign-currency analogy, the process 𝑆 can be viewed as a spot interest rate spread expressed as a ratio between the short rates 𝑓 𝑑 (𝑡, 𝑡)/𝑓 𝑓 (𝑡, 𝑡). In order to rule out arbitrage between investments in the domestic (discounting) and foreign (forwarding) assets, we shall refer to the no-arbitrage conditions in (I) and (II), in particular  There exits a probability measure measure ℙ̃ equivalent to ℙ on (Ω, 𝔽 𝑇∗̃ ) such that the the foreign money account 𝐵𝑡 𝑓 when expressed in domestic currency (𝐵𝑡 𝑓 𝑆𝑡) and discounted by the domestic money account 𝐵𝑡 𝑑 is a martingale under the domestic (discounting) risk neutral measure ℙ̃ 𝑑.  There exits a probability measure measure ℙ̃ equivalent to ℙ on (Ω, 𝔽 𝑇∗̃ ) such that the the foreign zero coupon bond 𝐵 𝑓(𝑡, 𝑇) when expressed in domestic currency (𝐵 𝑓(𝑡, 𝑇)𝑆𝑡) and discounted by the domestic money account 𝐵𝑡 𝑑 is a martingale under the domestic (discounting) risk neutral measure ℙ̃ 𝑑. Using the 𝐼𝑡𝑜̃ product and quotient rules, we have 𝜕(𝐵𝑡 𝑓 𝑆𝑡)/𝐵𝑡 𝑑 (𝐵𝑡 𝑓 𝑆𝑡)/𝐵𝑡 𝑑 = 𝜕𝐵𝑡 𝑓 𝐵𝑡 𝑓 + 𝜕𝑆𝑡 𝑆𝑡 − 𝜕𝐵𝑡 𝑑 𝐵𝑡 𝑑 + 𝑐𝑜𝑣𝑎𝑟𝑖𝑎𝑛𝑐𝑒 𝑡𝑒𝑟𝑚𝑠⏟ =0 treated as an non-increasing function with 𝑆𝑡 > 0 for any 𝑡 and 𝑆0 = 1.
  • 8.  On HJM Model and Its Extension to Single-Currency-Multiple-Curves Modelling Page 8 of 13 = 𝑟𝑡 𝑓 𝑑𝑡 + 𝜇 𝑡 𝑑𝑡 + 𝜎𝑡 𝑠 𝑑 − 𝑟𝑡 𝑑 𝑑𝑡 = 𝜎𝑡 𝑠 (𝜃𝑡 𝑑𝑡 + 𝑑𝑊̃ 𝑆(𝑡)) where 𝜃𝑡 = 𝑟𝑡 𝑓 − 𝑟𝑡 𝑑 + 𝜇 𝑡 𝜎𝑡 𝑠 is the market price of risk satisfying condition (I). By the Girsanov’s Theorem in (15), we have 𝑊̃ 𝑆 𝑑 (𝑡) = 𝑊̃ 𝑆(𝑡) − ∫ 𝜃 𝑢 𝑡 0 𝑑𝑢 ∀ 𝑡 ∈ [0, 𝑇∗ ] and 𝜕(𝐵𝑡 𝑓 𝑆𝑡)/𝐵𝑡 𝑑 (𝐵𝑡 𝑓 𝑆𝑡)/𝐵𝑡 𝑑 = 𝜎𝑡 𝑠 𝑑𝑊̃ 𝑆 𝑑 (𝑡) (34) Multiplying equation (34) by 𝐵𝑡 𝑑 /𝐵𝑡 𝑓 and by the 𝐼𝑡𝑜̃ rules, we have the dynamics of the spot “exchange” rate under the domestic (discounting) risk neutral measure ℙ̃ 𝑑 𝜕𝑆𝑡 𝑆𝑡 = (𝑟𝑡 𝑑 − 𝑟𝑡 𝑓 )𝑑𝑡 + 𝜎𝑡 𝑠 𝑑𝑊̃ 𝑆 𝑑 (𝑡) = [𝑓 𝑑 (𝑡, 𝑡) − 𝑓 𝑓 (𝑡, 𝑡)]𝑑𝑡 + 𝜎𝑡 𝑠 𝑑𝑊̃ 𝑆 𝑑 (𝑡) (35) Similarly, for the foreign bond process, we have 𝜕(𝐵 𝑓(𝑡, 𝑇)𝑆𝑡)/𝐵𝑡 𝑑 (𝐵 𝑓(𝑡, 𝑇)𝑆𝑡)/𝐵𝑡 𝑑 = 𝜕𝐵 𝑓(𝑡, 𝑇) 𝐵 𝑓(𝑡, 𝑇) + 𝜕𝑆𝑡 𝑆𝑡 + 𝜕[𝐵 𝑓(𝑡, 𝑇), 𝑆𝑡] 𝐵 𝑓(𝑡, 𝑇)𝑆𝑡 − 𝜕𝐵𝑡 𝑑 𝐵𝑡 𝑑 + 𝑐𝑜𝑣𝑎𝑟𝑖𝑎𝑛𝑐𝑒 𝑡𝑒𝑟𝑚𝑠⏟ =0 = 𝑟𝑡 𝑓 𝑑𝑡 − Σ 𝑓(𝑡, 𝑇)𝑑𝑊̃ 𝑓(𝑡) + (𝑟𝑡 𝑑 − 𝑟𝑡 𝑓 )𝑑𝑡 + 𝜎𝑡 𝑠 𝑑𝑊̃𝑠 𝑑 (𝑡) − Σ 𝑓(𝑡, 𝑇)𝑑𝑊̃ 𝑓(𝑡)𝜎𝑡 𝑠 𝑑𝑊̃𝑠 𝑑 (𝑡) − 𝑟𝑡 𝑑 𝑑𝑡 = −Σ 𝑓(𝑡, 𝑇) 𝜎𝑡 𝑠 𝜌𝑡 𝐵 𝑓,𝑠 𝑑𝑡 − Σ 𝑓(𝑡, 𝑇)𝑑𝑊̃𝑓 (𝑡) + 𝜎𝑡 𝑠 𝑑𝑊̃𝑠 𝑑(𝑡) (36) where 〈𝑊̃ 𝑓, 𝑊̃ 𝑆 𝑑 〉 = 𝜌𝑡 𝐵 𝑓,𝑠 is the instantaneous correlation between relative changes in 𝐵 𝑓(∙, 𝑇) and 𝑆. Moreover, using the fact that the sum of two martingales under ℙ̃ 𝑑 is a martingale under ℙ̃ 𝑑 , we can derive the Brownian motion of the foreign bond process in the domestic measure as 𝑊̃𝑓 𝑑 (𝑡) = 𝑊̃𝑓(𝑡) + ∫ 𝜎 𝑢 𝑠 𝜌 𝑢 𝐵 𝑓,𝑠 𝑡 0 𝑑𝑢 ∀ 𝑡 ∈ [0, 𝑇∗ ] 7 From German et al. (1995), Musiela and Rutkowski (2005), and Shreve (2004), the forward price of an asset is Thus, 𝜕𝐵 𝑓(𝑡, 𝑇) 𝐵 𝑓(𝑡, 𝑇) = [𝑟𝑡 𝑓 + Σ 𝑓(𝑡, 𝑇)𝜎𝑡 𝑠 𝜌𝑡 𝐵 𝑓,𝑠 ] 𝑑𝑡 − Σ 𝑓(𝑡, 𝑇)𝑑𝑊̃ 𝑓 𝑑 (𝑡) (37) and the dynamics of the foreign (forwarding) forward curve in domestic (discounting) measure can be derived by solving equation (37) for ln 𝐵(𝑡, 𝑇) and by equation (1), namely 𝑓 𝑓(𝑡, 𝑇) = − 𝜕 𝑇 ln 𝐵 𝑓(𝑡, 𝑇) where 𝜕 ln 𝐵 𝑓(𝑡, 𝑇) = (𝑟𝑡 𝑓 + Σ 𝑓(𝑡, 𝑇)𝜎𝑡 𝑠 𝜌𝑡 𝐵 𝑓,𝑠 − 1 2 |Σ 𝑓(𝑡, 𝑇)| 2 ) 𝑑𝑡 − Σ 𝑓(𝑡, 𝑇)𝑑𝑊̃ 𝑓 𝑑 (𝑡) and ln 𝐵 𝑓(𝑡, 𝑇) = ln 𝐵 𝑓(0, 𝑇) + ∫ ( (𝑟𝑢 𝑓 + Σ 𝑓(𝑢, 𝑇)𝜎 𝑢 𝑠 𝜌 𝑢 𝐵 𝑓,𝑠 − 1 2 |Σ 𝑓(𝑢, 𝑇)| 2 ) 𝑑𝑢 − Σ 𝑓(𝑢, 𝑇)𝑑𝑊̃𝑓 𝑑 (𝑢) ) 𝑡 0 and 𝑓 𝑓(𝑡, 𝑇) = 𝑓 𝑓(0, 𝑇) − ∫ (𝜎 𝑓(𝑢, 𝑇) ∫ 𝜎 𝑓(𝑢, 𝑠)𝑑𝑠 + 𝑇 𝑡 𝑡 0 𝜎 𝑓(𝑢, 𝑇)𝜎 𝑢 𝑠 𝜌 𝑢 𝐵 𝑓,𝑠 ) 𝑑𝑢 + ∫ 𝜎 𝑓(𝑢, 𝑇)𝑑𝑊̃𝑓 𝑑 (𝑢) 𝑡 0 (38) which is the instantaneous forward rate for the forwarding curve under the discounting risk-neutral probability measure ℙ̃ 𝑑. From Martinez (2009) and Grbac and Runggaldier (2015), the HJM drift condition in equation (38) under ℙ̃ 𝑑 can be derived directly by 𝜕 𝑇 [−⋀ 𝑓(𝑡, 𝑇) + 1 2 |Σ 𝑓(𝑡, 𝑇)| 2 ] = 𝜕 𝑇[〈 𝜎𝑡 𝑠 , Σ 𝑓(𝑡, 𝑇)〉] (39) 4.3 Forward Measure As with many derivatives such as FX options, FRAs are written on the forward rates instead of spot rates. Hence, in order to price a forward contract under the no-arbitrage framework, we need to apply the forward probability measure7 . Recall that we are interested in calculating the expectation in (29), namely 𝔼 𝑡 ℙ̃ 𝑑 𝑇+𝛿 (𝐿(𝑇, 𝑇 + 𝛿)|ℱ𝑡) = 𝔼 𝑡 ℙ̃ 𝑑 𝑇+𝛿 (𝐹𝑓(𝑇, 𝑇, 𝑇 + 𝛿)|ℱ𝑡) which allows one to price the FRA in a single-currency- double-curves framework at time 𝑡 for settlement date a martingale under the forward probability measure associated with the settlement date of the forward contract.
  • 9.  On HJM Model and Its Extension to Single-Currency-Multiple-Curves Modelling Page 9 of 13 𝑇 + 𝛿 using the artificial risky bonds 𝐵 𝑓(𝑡, ∙ ) and the spot “exchange” rate 𝑆𝑡. From Musiela and Rutkowski (2005), the forward process of the zero bonds for the time interval [𝑇, 𝑇 + 𝛿] is given by 𝐹𝐵(𝑡, 𝑇, 𝑇 + 𝛿) ≝ 𝐵(𝑡, 𝑇) 𝐵(𝑡, 𝑇 + 𝛿) ∀ 𝑡 ∈ [0, 𝑇] (40) and the 𝑥 - 𝑇 + 𝛿 - forward prices are martingales under the 𝑥 - 𝑇 + 𝛿 - forward measure ℙ̃ 𝑥 𝑇+𝛿 , 𝑥 = {𝑑, 𝑓}. By 𝐼𝑡𝑜̃ quotient rule, we have 𝐹𝐵 𝑥 (𝑡, 𝑇, 𝑇 + 𝛿) = 𝜕(𝐵 𝑥(𝑡, 𝑇)/𝐵 𝑥(𝑡, 𝑇 + 𝛿)) 𝐵 𝑥(𝑡, 𝑇)/𝐵 𝑥(𝑡, 𝑇 + 𝛿) = 𝜕𝐵 𝑥(𝑡, 𝑇) 𝐵 𝑥(𝑡, 𝑇) − 𝜕𝐵 𝑥(𝑡, 𝑇 + 𝛿) 𝐵 𝑥(𝑡, 𝑇 + 𝛿) + 𝜕[𝐵 𝑥(𝑡, 𝑇 + 𝛿), 𝐵 𝑥(𝑡, 𝑇 + 𝛿)] (𝐵 𝑥(𝑡, 𝑇 + 𝛿)) 2 − 𝜕[𝐵 𝑥(𝑡, 𝑇), 𝐵 𝑥(𝑡, 𝑇 + 𝛿)] 𝐵 𝑥(𝑡, 𝑇)𝐵 𝑥(𝑡, 𝑇 + 𝛿) = (Σ 𝑥(𝑡, 𝑇 + 𝛿) − Σ 𝑥(𝑡, 𝑇))𝑑𝑊̃𝑥 𝑥(𝑡) +(|Σ 𝑥(𝑡, 𝑇 + 𝛿)|2 − Σ 𝑥(𝑡, 𝑇)Σ 𝑥(𝑡, 𝑇 + 𝛿))𝑑𝑡 (41) which we assumed, for simplicity, that the forward volatilities (Σ 𝑥(𝑡, 𝑇 + 𝛿) − Σ 𝑥(𝑡, 𝑇)) are bounded. The drift term in equation (41) is not equal zero because 𝑊̃𝑥 𝑥 (𝑡) is a Brownian motion under the 𝑥 - risk-neutral measure instead of a Brownian motion under x - 𝑇 + 𝛿 forward measure ℙ̃ 𝑥 𝑇+𝛿 . Therefore, the 𝑅𝑎𝑑𝑜𝑛 - 𝑁𝑖𝑘𝑜𝑑𝑦́ 𝑚 𝑑𝑒𝑟𝑖𝑣𝑎𝑡𝑖𝑣𝑒 gives 𝜕ℙ̃ 𝑥 𝑇+𝛿 𝜕ℙ̃ 𝑥 = exp (− ∫ 𝑟𝑢 𝑥 𝑑𝑢 𝑇+𝛿 0 ) 𝐵 𝑥(0, 𝑇 + 𝛿) = 1 𝐵 𝑥(0, 𝑇 + 𝛿)𝐵 𝑇+𝛿 𝑥 = ℇ 𝑇+𝛿 (− ∫ Σ 𝑥(𝑢, 𝑇 + 𝛿) ∙ 0 𝑑𝑊̃𝑥 𝑥 (𝑢)) ℙ̃ 𝑥 − 𝑎. 𝑠. (42) (Musiela and Rutkowski, 1997; Shreve, 2004) which implies that moving to the 𝑥 - 𝑇 + 𝛿 - forward measure on (Ω, 𝔽 𝑇+𝛿) amounts to changing the numeraire from the saving account 𝐵 𝑇+𝛿 𝑥 to the zero-coupon bond 𝐵 𝑥(0, 𝑇 + 𝛿). Moreover, by Girsanov’s Theorem 𝑊̃𝑥 𝑥,𝑇+𝛿 (𝑡) = 𝑊̃𝑥 𝑥(𝑡) + ∫ Σ 𝑥(𝑢, 𝑇 + 𝛿)𝑑𝑢 𝑡 0 (43) which gives the Brownian motion under the 𝑥 - forward martingale measure for the settlement date 𝑇 + 𝛿 associated with the 𝑥 - 𝑇 + 𝛿 - maturity zero-coupon bond as a numeraire. From Musiela and Rutkowski (1997), the above derivations satisfy the no-arbitrage condition if the forward bond processes 𝐹𝐵(𝑡, 𝑇, 𝑇 + 𝛿) > 1, otherwise the processes are said to satisfy the weak no-arbitrage condition. Nevertheless, the 𝑥 zero bonds under the 𝑥 - 𝑇 + 𝛿 - forward martingale measure can be summarized as follows 𝜕𝐵 𝑓(𝑡, 𝑇) 𝐵 𝑓(𝑡, 𝑇) = (𝑟𝑡 𝑓 + Σ 𝑓(𝑡, 𝑇)Σ 𝑓(𝑡, 𝑇 + 𝛿)) 𝑑𝑡 − Σ 𝑓(𝑡, 𝑇)𝑑𝑊̃𝑓 𝑓,𝑇+𝛿 (𝑡) (44) 𝜕𝐵 𝑑(𝑡, 𝑇 + 𝛿) 𝐵 𝑑(𝑡, 𝑇 + 𝛿) = (𝑟𝑡 𝑑 + |Σ 𝑑(𝑡, 𝑇 + 𝛿)|2)𝑑𝑡 − Σ 𝑑(𝑡, 𝑇 + 𝛿)𝑑𝑊̃𝑑 𝑑,𝑇+𝛿 (𝑡) (45) Before devolving into the dynamics of the foreign (forwarding) curve, let us first consider a foreign exchange forward contact written at time 𝑡 for settlement at time 𝑇. By the interest rate parity, the interest rate differential between the domestic and foreign economies must equal to the difference between the forward exchange rate and spot exchange rate. Therefore, we have the forward exchange rate given by 𝐹𝑆(𝑡, 𝑇) = e(𝑟 𝑑−𝑟 𝑓)(𝑇−𝑡) 𝑆𝑡 = 𝐵 𝑓(𝑡, 𝑇) 𝐵 𝑑(𝑡, 𝑇) 𝑆𝑡 ∀ 𝑡 ∈ [0, 𝑇] (46) Forward FX-rate (Musiela and Rutkowski, 2005:p.155) Applying this analogy to our case, we are interested in deriving a forward process that is consistent with the expectation in (29), namely a forward “exchange” rate 𝐹𝑆(𝑡, 𝑇, 𝑇 + 𝛿) at time 𝑡 for the time interval [𝑡, 𝑇] and for settlement date 𝑇 + 𝛿. Accordingly, one is naturally led to look at the ratio 𝐹𝑆(𝑡, 𝑇, 𝑇 + 𝛿) = 𝐵 𝑓(𝑡, 𝑇) 𝐵 𝑑(𝑡, 𝑇 + 𝛿) 𝑆𝑡 ∀ 𝑡 ∈ [0, 𝑇] (47) This derivation follows directly from the 𝑅𝑎𝑑𝑜𝑛 - 𝑁𝑖𝑘𝑜𝑑𝑦́ 𝑚 𝑑𝑒𝑟𝑖𝑣𝑎𝑡𝑖𝑣𝑒 in (42) that under the domestic (discounting) - 𝑇 + 𝛿 - forward measure, the forward “exchange” rate associated to the numeraire 𝐵 𝑑(𝑡, 𝑇 + 𝛿) is a martingale under ℙ̃ 𝑑 𝑇+𝛿 , assuming that 𝐵 𝑓(𝑡, 𝑇)𝑆𝑡 is a domestic tradable asset. Yet, before deriving the dynamics of equation (47), let us first change the measure of the spot “exchange” rate 𝑆𝑡 under ℙ̃ 𝑑 to ℙ̃ 𝑑 𝑇+𝛿 𝜕(𝑆𝑡 𝐵𝑡 𝑓 )/𝐵 𝑑(𝑡, 𝑇 + 𝛿) (𝑆𝑡 𝐵𝑡 𝑓 )/𝐵 𝑑(𝑡, 𝑇 + 𝛿) = 𝜕𝑆𝑡 𝑆𝑡 + 𝜕𝐵𝑡 𝑓 𝐵𝑡 𝑓 − 𝜕𝐵 𝑑(𝑡, 𝑇 + 𝛿) 𝐵 𝑑(𝑡, 𝑇 + 𝛿) + [𝜕𝐵 𝑑(𝑡, 𝑇 + 𝛿)]2 (𝐵 𝑑(𝑡, 𝑇 + 𝛿)) 2 − 𝜕𝑆𝑡 𝐵𝑡 𝑓 𝑆𝑡 𝐵𝑡 𝑓 𝜕𝐵 𝑑(𝑡, 𝑇 + 𝛿) 𝐵 𝑑(𝑡, 𝑇 + 𝛿) = (𝑟𝑡 𝑑 − 𝑟𝑡 𝑓 )𝑑𝑡 + 𝜎𝑡 𝑠 𝑑𝑊̃ 𝑆 𝑑 (𝑡) + 𝑟𝑡 𝑓 𝑑𝑡 − (𝑟𝑡 𝑑 + |Σ 𝑑(𝑡, 𝑇 + 𝛿)|2)𝑑𝑡 + Σ 𝑑(𝑡, 𝑇 + 𝛿)𝑑𝑊̃ 𝑑 𝑑,𝑇+𝛿 (𝑡) + |Σ 𝑑(𝑡, 𝑇 + 𝛿)|2 𝑑𝑡 + 𝜌𝑡 𝐵 𝑑,𝑆 𝜎𝑡 𝑠 Σ 𝑑(𝑡, 𝑇 + 𝛿)𝑑𝑡
  • 10.  On HJM Model and Its Extension to Single-Currency-Multiple-Curves Modelling Page 10 of 13 = 𝜎𝑡 𝑠 (𝑑𝑊̃ 𝑆 𝑑 (𝑡) + {𝜌𝑡 𝐵 𝑑,𝑆 Σ 𝑑(𝑡, 𝑇 + 𝛿)} 𝑑𝑡) + Σ 𝑑(𝑡, 𝑇 + 𝛿)𝑑𝑊̃ 𝑑 𝑑,𝑇+𝛿 (𝑡) we therefore have 𝑊̃𝑆 𝑑,𝑇+𝛿 (𝑡) = 𝑊̃ 𝑆 𝑑 (𝑡) + ∫ 𝜌 𝑢 𝐵 𝑑,𝑆 Σ 𝑑(𝑢, 𝑇 + 𝛿) 𝑡 0 𝑑𝑢 and the spot “exchange” rate 𝑆𝑡 under the domestic (discounting) - 𝑇 + 𝛿 - forward measure 𝜕𝑆𝑡 𝑆𝑡 = (𝑟𝑡 𝑑 − 𝑟𝑡 𝑓 − 𝜌𝑡 𝐵 𝑑,𝑆 𝜎𝑡 𝑠 Σ 𝑑(𝑡, 𝑇 + 𝛿))𝑑𝑡 + 𝜎𝑡 𝑠 𝑑𝑊̃𝑠 𝑑,𝑇+𝛿 (𝑡) (48) Following from above, we can derive the forward process for 𝐹𝑆(𝑡, 𝑇, 𝑇 + 𝛿) as 𝜕(𝑆𝑡 𝐵 𝑓(𝑡, 𝑇))/𝐵 𝑑(𝑡, 𝑇 + 𝛿) (𝑆𝑡 𝐵 𝑓(𝑡, 𝑇))/𝐵 𝑑(𝑡, 𝑇 + 𝛿) = (𝑟𝑡 𝑑 − 𝑟𝑡 𝑓 − 𝜌𝑡 𝐵 𝑑,𝑆 𝜎𝑡 𝑠 Σ 𝑑(𝑡, 𝑇 + 𝛿)) 𝑑𝑡 +𝜎𝑡 𝑠 𝑑𝑊̃𝑠 𝑑,𝑇+𝛿 (𝑡) + (𝑟𝑡 𝑓 + Σ 𝑓(𝑡, 𝑇)Σ 𝑓(𝑡, 𝑇 + 𝛿)) 𝑑𝑡 − Σ 𝑓(𝑡, 𝑇)𝑑𝑊̃𝑓 𝑓,𝑇+𝛿 (𝑡) − (𝑟𝑡 𝑑 + |Σ 𝑑(𝑡, 𝑇 + 𝛿)|2)𝑑𝑡 + Σ 𝑑(𝑡, 𝑇 + 𝛿)𝑑𝑊̃𝑑 𝑑,𝑇+𝛿 (𝑡) + |Σ 𝑑(𝑡, 𝑇 + 𝛿)|2 𝑑𝑡 − Σ 𝑓(𝑡, 𝑇)𝜎𝑡 𝑠 𝜌𝑡 𝐵 𝑓,𝑆 𝑑𝑡 + Σ 𝑓(𝑡, 𝑇)Σ 𝑑(𝑡, 𝑇 + 𝛿)𝜌𝑡 𝐵 𝑑,𝐵 𝑓 𝑑𝑡 + 𝜌𝑡 𝐵 𝑑,𝑆 𝜎𝑡 𝑠 Σ 𝑑(𝑡, 𝑇 + 𝛿) = −Σ 𝑓(𝑡, 𝑇)( 𝑑𝑊̃𝑓 𝑓,𝑇+𝛿 (𝑡) − {(Σ 𝑓(𝑡, 𝑇 + 𝛿) + Σ 𝑑(𝑡, 𝑇 + 𝛿)𝜌𝑡 𝐵 𝑑,𝐵 𝑓 − 𝜎𝑡 𝑠 𝜌𝑡 𝐵 𝑓,𝑆 ) 𝑑𝑡} + Σ 𝑑(𝑡, 𝑇 + 𝛿)𝑑𝑊̃𝑑 𝑑,𝑇+𝛿 (𝑡) + 𝜎𝑡 𝑠 𝑑𝑊̃𝑠 𝑑,𝑇+𝛿 (𝑡) which implies 𝜕ℙ̃ 𝑓 𝑑,𝑇+𝛿 𝜕ℙ̃ 𝑓 𝑓,𝑇+𝛿 = ℇ 𝑇+𝛿 (− ∫ { Σ 𝑓(𝑢, 𝑇 + 𝛿) +Σ 𝑑(𝑢, 𝑇 + 𝛿)𝜌 𝑢 𝐵 𝑑,𝐵 𝑓 −𝜎 𝑢 𝑠 𝜌 𝑢 𝐵 𝑓,𝑆 𝑑𝑊̃𝑓 𝑓,𝑇+𝛿 (𝑢) } ∙ 0 ) ℙ̃ 𝑓 𝑓,𝑇+𝛿 − 𝑎. 𝑠. (49) and 𝑊̃𝑓 𝑑,𝑇+𝛿 (𝑡) = 𝑊̃𝑓 𝑓,𝑇+𝛿 (𝑡) − ∫ (Σ 𝑓(𝑢, 𝑇 + 𝛿) + Σ 𝑑(𝑢, 𝑇 + 𝛿)𝜌 𝑢 𝐵 𝑑,𝐵 𝑓 − 𝜎 𝑢 𝑠 𝜌 𝑢 𝐵 𝑓,𝑆 ) 𝑡 0 𝑑𝑢 (50) where 𝑊̃𝑓 𝑑,𝑇+𝛿 (𝑡) is the Brownian motion of the foreign (forwarding) bond under the domestic (discounting) - 𝑇 + 𝛿 - forward measure. Hence, the foreign (reference) bond process under ℙ̃ 𝑑 𝑇+𝛿 is 𝜕𝐵 𝑓(𝑡, 𝑇) 𝐵 𝑓(𝑡, 𝑇) = (𝑟𝑡 𝑓 − Σ 𝑓(𝑡, 𝑇) {Σ 𝑑(𝑡, 𝑇 + 𝛿)𝜌𝑡 𝐵 𝑑,𝐵 𝑓 − 𝜎𝑡 𝑠 𝜌𝑡 𝐵 𝑓,𝑆 }) 𝑑𝑡 − Σ 𝑓(𝑡, 𝑇)𝑑𝑊̃𝑓 𝑑,𝑇+𝛿 (𝑡) (51) Solving equation (51) for ln 𝐵 𝑓(𝑡, 𝑇) and differentiating with respect to 𝑇, 𝜕 𝑇 ln 𝐵 𝑓(𝑡, 𝑇), would give the dynamics of the instantaneous forward rate process for the forwarding curve 𝑓 𝑓( ∙ , 𝑇) under ℙ̃ 𝑑 𝑇+𝛿 . However, such derivation is not necessary as we could price the FRA in term of a quanto correction – a procedure typical to the pricing of cross-currency derivatives. 4.3 Pricing Under Single-Currency-Double Curves Having derived the 𝑅𝑎𝑑𝑜𝑛 - 𝑁𝑖𝑘𝑜𝑑𝑦́ 𝑚 𝑑𝑒𝑛𝑠𝑖𝑡𝑦 in equation (49), we can proceed to calculate the expectation in (29). In a single-currency-double-curves framework, this amounts to transforming a cash-flow on the forwarding curve to the corresponding discounting curve (Bianchetti, 2009). Thus, we have the Libor rate given by the following 𝔼 𝑡 ℙ̃ 𝑑 𝑇+𝛿 (𝐿(𝑇, 𝑇 + 𝛿)) = 𝔼 𝑡 ℙ̃ 𝑑 𝑇+𝛿 (𝐹𝑓(𝑇, 𝑇, 𝑇 + 𝛿)) = 1 𝛿 (𝔼 𝑡 ℙ̃ 𝑑 𝑇+𝛿 [ 𝐵 𝑓(𝑡, 𝑇) 𝐵 𝑓(𝑡, 𝑇 + 𝛿) ] − 1) = 1 𝛿 (𝔼 𝑡 ℙ̃ 𝑑 𝑇+𝛿 [𝐹𝐵 𝑓 (𝑇, 𝑇, 𝑇 + 𝛿)] − 1) (52) From (41) and (50), under the domestic (discounting) forward measure, we have the foreign (forwarding) forward bond price given by 𝜕𝐹𝐵 𝑓 (𝑡, 𝑇, 𝑇 + 𝛿) = (Σ 𝑓(𝑡, 𝑇 + 𝛿) − Σ 𝑓(𝑡, 𝑇)) 𝑑𝑊̃𝑓 𝑓,𝑇+𝛿 (𝑡) = (Σ 𝑓(𝑡, 𝑇 + 𝛿) − Σ 𝑓(𝑡, 𝑇)) {𝑑𝑊̃𝑓 𝑑,𝑇+𝛿 (𝑡) + ( Σ 𝑓(𝑡, 𝑇 + 𝛿) + Σ 𝑑(𝑡, 𝑇 + 𝛿)𝜌𝑡 𝐵 𝑑,𝐵 𝑓 − 𝜎𝑡 𝑠 𝜌𝑡 𝐵 𝑓,𝑆 ) 𝑑𝑡} (53) and 𝔼 𝑡 ℙ̃ 𝑑 𝑇+𝛿 (𝐹𝐵 𝑓 (𝑇, 𝑇, 𝑇 + 𝛿)) = 𝐹𝐵 𝑓 (𝑡, 𝑇, 𝑇 + 𝛿) 𝑒𝑥𝑝 ( ∫ ( (Σ 𝑓(𝑢, 𝑇 + 𝛿) − Σ 𝑓(𝑢, 𝑇)) {( Σ 𝑓(𝑢, 𝑇 + 𝛿) + Σ 𝑑(𝑢, 𝑇 + 𝛿)𝜌 𝑢 𝐵 𝑑,𝐵 𝑓 −𝜎 𝑢 𝑠 𝜌 𝑢 𝐵 𝑓,𝑆 )} ) 𝑇 𝑡 𝑑𝑢 )⏟ 𝑄𝑢𝑎𝑛𝑡𝑜 𝑐𝑜𝑟𝑟𝑒𝑐𝑡𝑖𝑜𝑛 (54)
  • 11.  On HJM Model and Its Extension to Single-Currency-Multiple-Curves Modelling Page 11 of 13 Hence, 𝔼 𝑡 ℙ̃ 𝑑 𝑇+𝛿 (𝐿(𝑇, 𝑇 + 𝛿)) = (1 + 𝛿 𝐹𝑓 𝑀 (𝑡, 𝑇, 𝑇 + 𝛿)) 𝑒𝑥𝑝 ( ∫ ( (Σ 𝑓(𝑢, 𝑇 + 𝛿) − Σ 𝑓(𝑢, 𝑇)) {( Σ 𝑓(𝑢, 𝑇 + 𝛿) + Σ 𝑑(𝑢, 𝑇 + 𝛿)𝜌 𝑢 𝐵 𝑑,𝐵 𝑓 −𝜎 𝑢 𝑠 𝜌 𝑢 𝐵 𝑓,𝑆 )} ) 𝑇 𝑡 𝑑𝑢 ) − 1 (55) where 𝐹𝑓 𝑀 (𝑡, 𝑇, 𝑇 + 𝛿) denotes the Libor rate for period {𝑇, 𝑇 + 𝛿}, observable at time t from market data. As shown in the above derivations, the expectation of 𝐹𝐵 𝑓 (𝑇, 𝑇, 𝑇 + 𝛿) has a quanto correction, which depends on the implied forward bond price volatilities and two correlation terms. This means that the FRA can be priced by discounting the cash-flow with the risk-free discount rate and adding a convexity adjustment factor – a procedure typical to the pricing of cross-currency products. Furthermore, one could simplify the derivations and obtain results similar to Bianchetti (2009) and Theis (2017) by modelling the quantity 𝐹𝑆(𝑡, 𝑇, 𝑇 + 𝛿) directly, and changing the measure of 𝐹𝐵 𝑓 (𝑡, 𝑇, 𝑇 + 𝛿) to ℙ̃ 𝑑 𝑇+𝛿 . Following from our foreign currency analogy and from Cuchiero, Fontana and Gnoatto (2014), let us consider the forward “exchange” rate for the time intervals [𝑡, 𝑇] and [𝑡, 𝑇 + 𝛿] 𝐹𝑆(𝑡, 𝑇) = 𝐵 𝑓(𝑡, 𝑇)𝑆𝑡 𝐵 𝑑(𝑡, 𝑇) and 𝐹𝑆(𝑡, 𝑇 + 𝛿) = 𝐵 𝑓(𝑡, 𝑇 + 𝛿)𝑆𝑡 𝐵 𝑑(𝑡, 𝑇 + 𝛿) The forward interest rate spread8 𝐹𝑆(𝑡, 𝑇, 𝑇 + 𝛿) can be derived by 𝐹𝑆(𝑡, 𝑇 + 𝛿) 𝐹𝑆(𝑡, 𝑇) = 𝐵 𝑓(𝑡, 𝑇 + 𝛿)𝑆𝑡 𝐵 𝑑(𝑡, 𝑇 + 𝛿) 𝐵 𝑑(𝑡, 𝑇) 𝐵 𝑓(𝑡, 𝑇)𝑆𝑡 From equation (46), we thus have 𝐹𝑆(𝑡, 𝑇, 𝑇 + 𝛿)𝐹𝐵 𝑓 (𝑡, 𝑇, 𝑇 + 𝛿) = 𝐹𝐵 𝑑 (𝑡, 𝑇, 𝑇 + 𝛿) (56) Notice, however, that different dynamics can be specified according to different interpretation of the quantity 𝐹𝑆(𝑡, 𝑇, 𝑇 + 𝛿). While Bianchetti (2009) and Theis (2017) use an FX analogy, Henrard (2010), Mercurio (2010), and Mercurio and Xie (2012) model it as a stochastic basis spread. Here we shall continue with our foreign exchange analogy and model 𝐹𝑆(𝑡, 𝑇, 𝑇 + 𝛿) as forward “exchange” rate consistent with equation (47), hence, 8 See Cuchiero, Fontana and Gnoatto (2014) Appendix B for proof and derivation. 𝐹𝑆(𝑡, 𝑇, 𝑇 + 𝛿) = 𝜎𝑡 𝑠 𝑑𝑊̃𝑠 𝑑,𝑇+𝛿 (𝑡) − Σ 𝑓(𝑡, 𝑇)𝑑𝑊̃𝑓 𝑑,𝑇+𝛿 (𝑡) + Σ 𝑑(𝑡, 𝑇 + 𝛿)𝑑𝑊̃𝑑 𝑑,𝑇+𝛿 (𝑡) (57) which is a martingale under ℙ̃ 𝑑 𝑇+𝛿 . Combining the forward “exchange” rate process into a single Brownian motion, we have 𝐹𝑆(𝑡, 𝑇, 𝑇 + 𝛿) = 𝜎𝑡 𝐹𝑠 𝑑𝑊̃𝐹𝑠 𝑑,𝑇+𝛿 (𝑡) (58) where 𝜎𝑡 𝐹𝑠 𝑑𝑊̃𝐹𝑠 𝑑,𝑇+𝛿 (𝑡) = 𝜎𝑡 𝑠 𝑑𝑊̃𝑠 𝑑,𝑇+𝛿 (𝑡) − Σ 𝑓(𝑡, 𝑇)𝑑𝑊̃𝑓 𝑑,𝑇+𝛿 (𝑡) + Σ 𝑑(𝑡, 𝑇 + 𝛿)𝑑𝑊̃ 𝑑 𝑑,𝑇+𝛿 (𝑡) (59) From the no-arbitrage conditions, we know that the process {𝐹𝑆(𝑡, 𝑇, 𝑇 + 𝛿)𝐹𝐵 𝑓 (𝑡, 𝑇, 𝑇 + 𝛿)} in (56) is a martingale under ℙ̃ 𝑑 𝑇+𝛿 . Hence, by 𝐼𝑡𝑜̃ product rule 𝜕𝐹𝑆(𝑡, 𝑇, 𝑇 + 𝛿)𝐹𝐵 𝑓 (𝑡, 𝑇, 𝑇 + 𝛿) 𝐹𝑆(𝑡, 𝑇, 𝑇 + 𝛿)𝐹𝐵 𝑓 (𝑡, 𝑇, 𝑇 + 𝛿) = 𝜕𝐹𝑆(𝑡, 𝑇, 𝑇 + 𝛿) 𝐹𝑆(𝑡, 𝑇, 𝑇 + 𝛿) + 𝜕𝐹𝐵 𝑓 (𝑡, 𝑇, 𝑇 + 𝛿) 𝐹𝐵 𝑓 (𝑡, 𝑇, 𝑇 + 𝛿) + 𝜕𝐹𝑆(𝑡, 𝑇, 𝑇 + 𝛿) 𝐹𝑆(𝑡, 𝑇, 𝑇 + 𝛿) 𝜕𝐹𝐵 𝑓 (𝑡, 𝑇, 𝑇 + 𝛿) 𝐹𝐵 𝑓 (𝑡, 𝑇, 𝑇 + 𝛿) = 𝜎𝑡 𝐹𝑠 𝑑𝑊̃𝐹𝑠 𝑑,𝑇+𝛿 (𝑡) + (Σ 𝑓(𝑡, 𝑇 + 𝛿) − Σ 𝑓(𝑡, 𝑇)) 𝑑𝑊̃𝑓 𝑓,𝑇+𝛿 (𝑡) + (Σ 𝑓(𝑡, 𝑇 + 𝛿) − Σ 𝑓(𝑡, 𝑇)) 𝜎𝑡 𝐹𝑠 𝜌𝑡 𝐵 𝑓,𝐹𝑠 𝑑𝑡 which gives 𝑊̃𝑓 𝑑,𝑇+𝛿 (𝑡) = 𝑊̃𝑓 𝑓,𝑇+𝛿 (𝑡) + ∫ 𝜎 𝑢 𝐹𝑠 𝜌 𝑢 𝐵 𝑓,𝐹𝑠 𝑡 0 𝑑𝑢 (60) Furthermore, from equation (41) and (60), we can derive 𝜕𝐹𝐵 𝑓 (𝑡, 𝑇, 𝑇 + 𝛿) = (Σ 𝑓(𝑡, 𝑇 + 𝛿) − Σ 𝑓(𝑡, 𝑇)) 𝑑𝑊̃𝑓 𝑓,𝑇+𝛿 (𝑡) = (Σ 𝑓(𝑡, 𝑇 + 𝛿) − Σ 𝑓(𝑡, 𝑇)) {𝑑𝑊̃𝑓 𝑑,𝑇+𝛿 (𝑡) − 𝜎𝑡 𝐹𝑠 𝜌𝑡 𝐵 𝑓,𝐹𝑠 𝑑𝑡} and thus 𝔼 𝑡 ℙ̃ 𝑑 𝑇+𝛿 (𝐿(𝑇, 𝑇 + 𝛿)) = (1 + 𝛿 𝐹𝑓 𝑀 (𝑡, 𝑇, 𝑇 + 𝛿)) 𝑒𝑥𝑝 ( − ∫ ((Σ 𝑓(𝑢, 𝑇 + 𝛿) − Σ 𝑓(𝑢, 𝑇)) 𝜎 𝑢 𝐹𝑠 𝜌 𝑢 𝐵 𝑓,𝐹𝑠 ) 𝑇 𝑡 𝑑𝑢 ⏟ 𝑄𝑢𝑎𝑛𝑡𝑜 𝑐𝑜𝑟𝑟𝑒𝑐𝑡𝑖𝑜𝑛 ) − 1 (61)
  • 12.  On HJM Model and Its Extension to Single-Currency-Multiple-Curves Modelling Page 12 of 13 In this derivation, the quanto correction depends on the implied foreign forward bond price volatility, the implied forward “exchange” rate volatility and the correlation between them. Moreover, since in equations (57)-(59) we have combined the forward “exchange” rate process into a single Brownian motion, the forward volatility 𝜎𝑡 𝐹𝑠 can be computed by 𝑉𝑎𝑟𝑡 ℙ̃ 𝑑 𝑇+𝛿 (𝐹𝑆(𝑇, 𝑇, 𝑇 + 𝛿)) = ∫ (𝜎𝑡 𝐹𝑠 𝑑𝑊̃𝐹𝑠 𝑑,𝑇+𝛿 (𝑡)) 2𝑇 𝑡 (𝜎𝑡 𝐹𝑠 𝑑𝑊̃𝐹𝑠 𝑑,𝑇+𝛿 (𝑡)) 2 = ( 𝜎𝑡 𝑠 𝑑𝑊̃𝑠 𝑑,𝑇+𝛿 (𝑡) − Σ 𝑓(𝑡, 𝑇)𝑑𝑊̃𝑓 𝑑,𝑇+𝛿 (𝑡) + Σ 𝑑(𝑡, 𝑇 + 𝛿)𝑑𝑊̃𝑑 𝑑,𝑇+𝛿 (𝑡) ) 2 which gives 𝜎𝑡 𝐹𝑠 = √{ (𝜎𝑡 𝑠)2 − 2𝜎𝑡 𝑠 Σ 𝑓(𝑡, 𝑇)𝜌𝑡 𝐵 𝑓,𝑆 +2𝜎𝑡 𝑠 Σ 𝑑(𝑡, 𝑇 + 𝛿)𝜌𝑡 𝐵 𝑑,𝑆 −2Σ 𝑓(𝑡, 𝑇)Σ 𝑑(𝑡, 𝑇 + 𝛿)𝜌𝑡 𝐵 𝑑,𝐵 𝑓 +|Σ 𝑓(𝑡, 𝑇)|2 + |Σ 𝑑(𝑡, 𝑇 + 𝛿)|2} (62) 5. Implementation and Estimation From the above equation, we can see that the implied volatility of the forward “exchange” rate can be calculated by integrating over the volatility functions. In Bianchetti (2009) and Hunter (2017), the spot volatility 𝜎𝑡 𝑠 is taken to be zero as the spot exchange rate9 in a single- currency-double-curves framework collapses to 1. In the HJM model, the volatilities Σ 𝑓 and Σ 𝑑 are stochastic and it would not be possible to estimate the quanto correction in (54) and (61). Thus, one would need to assume a Gaussian structure, in which Σ 𝑓 and Σ 𝑑 are deterministic (Theis, 2017). Nevertheless, the parameters of the qunato correction in equations (54) and (61) can be extracted from market data. In particular, the forward Libor rate volatilities can be derived from quoted cap/floor options corresponding to the maturity date T and tenor 𝛿. For 𝜎𝑡 𝐹𝑠 and 𝜌𝑡 𝐵 𝑓,𝐹𝑠 and for other tenors where there are no options available, one shall resort to historical data (Bianchetti, 2009). Moreover, using equation (62), one could also bootstrap out a term structure for 𝜎𝑡 𝐹𝑠 with Σ 𝑓 and Σ 𝑑 extracted from market data. Conversely, since the forward “exchange” rate in (46) is the exponential of ∫ 𝑓 𝑑(𝑡, 𝑢)𝑑𝑢 − ∫ 𝑓 𝑓(𝑡, 𝑢)𝑑𝑢 ∙ 𝑡 ∙ 𝑡 , its volatility and correlation with the forwarding rates can be implied from the behaviour of the spread (Theis, 2017). Having introduced the OIS rates in Section 4, let us consider the calculation of the OIS rates. An overnight indexed swap (OIS) is a contract in which two counterparties exchange a fixed rate 𝐾 with a floating 9 While the spot rate 𝑆𝑡 in Bianchetti (2009) is unspecified, the spot rate in Morini (2009) using the same analogy is modelled as survival probability. compounded overnight rate (i.e. Fed Funds Effective Rate for US Dollars and EONIA for Euros). From Brigo and Mercurio (2006) and Cuchiero, Fontana and Gnoatto (2014), the pricing formula with $1 notional is given by OIS(𝑡, 𝑇, 𝑇 𝑛 , 𝐾) = 𝐵 𝑂𝐼𝑆(𝑡, 𝑇) − 𝐵 𝑂𝐼𝑆(𝑡, 𝑇 𝑛) − 𝐾𝛿 ∑ 𝐵 𝑂𝐼𝑆(𝑡, 𝑇 𝑖) 𝑛 𝑖=1 where 𝛿 in here is the payment frequency, typically 1-year for the USD and EUR markets. 𝑇1 , … , 𝑇 𝑛 are the payment dates and 𝑇 𝑖+1 − 𝑇 𝑖 = 𝛿 for every 𝑖 = 1, … , 𝑛 − 1 . Moreover, the floating rate received at time 𝑇 𝑖+1 is set at time 𝑇 𝑖 . Thus at every time 𝑇 𝑖 , one party pays 𝛿𝐾 while the other party pays 𝛿𝑅 𝑂𝐼𝑆 (𝑇 𝑖 , 𝑇 𝑖+1 ) , where 𝑅 𝑂𝐼𝑆 (𝑇 𝑖 , 𝑇 𝑖+1 ) is the compounded OIS rate for the period [𝑇 𝑖 , 𝑇 𝑖+1 ] given by 𝑅 𝑂𝐼𝑆(𝑇 𝑖 , 𝑇 𝑖+1) = 𝛿−1 (∏ (1 + (𝑡 𝑗+1 − 𝑡 𝑗)𝑅 𝑂𝐼𝑆(𝑡 𝑗 , 𝑡 𝑗+1)) − 1 𝑘 𝑗=0 ) (63) and 𝑇 𝑖 = 𝑡0 < 𝑡1 < ⋯ < 𝑡 𝑘 = 𝑇 𝑖+1 denotes the partition of the period [𝑇 𝑖 , 𝑇 𝑖+1 ] into 𝑘 business days and 𝑅 𝑂𝐼𝑆(𝑡 𝑗 , 𝑡 𝑗+1) denotes the respective OIS rates over the interval [𝑡 𝑗 , 𝑡 𝑗+1 ]. OIS compounded rate (Filipovic and Trolle, 2013:p.12) Thus, the strike 𝐾 or the OIS rate that makes the swap fair at inception date 𝑡 with maturity date 𝑇 and 𝑛 payment dates is given by 𝑂𝐼𝑆(𝑡, 𝑇, 𝑛) = 𝐾 = 𝐵 𝑂𝐼𝑆 (𝑡, 𝑇) − 𝐵 𝑂𝐼𝑆 (𝑡, 𝑇 𝑛 ) 𝛿 ∑ 𝐵 𝑂𝐼𝑆(𝑡, 𝑇 𝑖)𝑛 𝑖=1 (64) Taking as example one leg of the swap, i.e., one payment. For 𝑛 = 1 and 𝑇 = 𝑇 𝑗 , equation (64) gives 𝑂𝐼𝑆(𝑡, 𝑇 𝑗 , 𝑛) = 𝐾 = 𝐵 𝑂𝐼𝑆 (𝑡, 𝑇 𝑗 ) − 𝐵 𝑂𝐼𝑆 (𝑡, 𝑇 𝑗+1 ) 𝛿𝐵 𝑂𝐼𝑆(𝑡, 𝑇 𝑗+1) (Musiela and Rutkowski, 1997) Thus, the term structure for the discount rates can be bootstrapped from market quotes of OIS. 6. Conclusion We have reviewed the derivations of the classical single-currency-single-curve HJM model, and how the credit crisis and the resulting inconsistencies between rates have forced the market to evolve to a valuation framework that incorporates multiple yield curves, namely, one for discounting and one for each Libor tenor. Following a foreign-currency analogy, we have also derived the
  • 13.  On HJM Model and Its Extension to Single-Currency-Multiple-Curves Modelling Page 13 of 13 dynamics of the discounting and forwarding curves. In particular, we have examined the pricing of FRA under a single-currency-double-curves valuation framework and a convexity adjustment factor, typical to the pricing of cross-currency derivatives, is derived as a result. Reference: Ametrano, F. M., and Bianchetti, M. (2013) Everything You Always Wanted to Know About Multiple Interest Rate Curve Bootstrapping But Were Afraid To Ask. Available from: http://ssrn.com/abstract=2219548 Brigo, D., and Mercurio, F. (2006) Interest Rate Models: Theory and Practice - with Smile, Inflation and Credit. Springer, Second Edition Bianchetti, M. (2009) Two Curves, One Price: Pricing ad Hedging Interest Rate Derivatives Using Different Yield Curves for Discounting and Forwarding. Available from: http://ssrn.com/abstract=1334356 Cox, J.C., Ingersoll, J.E., and Ross, S.A. (1985) A theory of the term structure of interest rates. Econometrica, vol. 53, pp. 385-407 Cuchiero, C., Fontana, C., and Gnoatto, A. (2015) A general HJM framework for multiple yield curve modelling. Finance and Stochastics, vol. 20, pp. 267–320. Available from: https://link.springer.com/article/10.1007/ s00780-016-0291-5 Dothan, L. (1978) On the term structure of interest rates. Journal of Financial Economics, vol. 6, pp. 59-69. Available from: https://www.sciencedirect.com/science/ article/pii/0304405X7890020X Filipovic, D., and Trolle, A. B. (2013) The term structure of interbank risk. Journal of Financial Economics, vol.109, pp. 707-733. Available from: http://www.sciencedirect.co m/science/article/pii/S0304405X13000949 Grbac, Z., and Runggaldier, W.J. (2015). Interest rate modeling: post-crisis challenges and approaches. Springer, First Edition Ho, T.S.Y., and Lee, S.B. (1986) Term structure movements and pricing interest rate contingent claims. Journal of Finance, vol. 41, pp. 1011-1029. Available from: http://www.jstor.org/stable/2328161?seq=1#page_scan_t ab_contents Hull, J., and White, A. (1990). Pricing interest rate derivatives securities. The Review of Financial Studies, vol. 3 pp. 573–592. Available from: https://doi.org/10.10 93/rfs/3.4.573 Heath, D., Jarrow, R., and Morton, A. (1992) Bond pricing and the term structure of interest rates: a new methodology for contingent claims valuation. Econometrica, vol. 60, pp. 77-105 Henrard, M. (2007). The Irony in the Derivatives Discounting. Wilmott Magazine, pp. 92-98 Henrard, M. (2012b) Multi-Curves: Variations on a Theme. Quantitative Research 6, OpenGamma. Available from: http://docs.opengamma.com Hunter, C. (2017) Introduction to Hybrid Modelling, Oxford Financial Mathematics. University of Oxford, Lecture notes, Advanced Modelling Topics 1 Musiela, M., and Rutkowski, M. (1997) Martingale methods in financial modelling. Springer, First Edition Musiela, M., and Rutkowski, M. (2005) Martingale methods in financial modelling. Springer, Second Edition Martìnez, T. (2009) Drift conditions on a HJM model with stochastic basis spreads. Available from: http://www.risk lab.es/es/jornadas/2009/index.html Mercurio, F. (2009). Interest Rates and The Credit Crunch: New Formulas and Market Models. Bloomberg Portfolio Research Paper No. 2010-01-FRONTIERS. Available from: http://ssrn.com/abstract=1332205 Morini, M. (2009). Solving the Puzzle in the Interest Rate Market. Available from: http://ssrn.com/abstract=15060 46 Moreni, N., and Pallavicini, A. (2010) Parsimonious HJM modelling for multiple yield-curve dynamics. Working paper, SSRN. Available from: http://ssrn.com/abstract=16 99300 Mercurio, F. (2010) LIBOR Market Models with Stochastic Basis. Available from: http://ssrn.com/abstract =1563685 Mercurio, F., and Xie, Z. (2012) The basis goes stochastic. Risk Magazine, pp. 78-83. Available from: https://www.ri sk.net/media/download/929966 Shreve, S.E. (2004) Stochastic Calculus for Finance II: Continuous-Time Models. Springer, First Edition Theis, J. (2017) Modelling Interest Rate Derivatives. University of Oxford, Lecture notes, Advanced Modelling Topics 1 Vasicek, O. (1977) An equilibrium characterisation of the term structure. Journal of Financial Economics, vol. 5, pp. 177-188