SlideShare a Scribd company logo
Islamic Republic of Afghanistan
Independent Directorate of Local Governance
Policy Paradigms, Subnational
Governance, and the State
Sovereignty Gap in Afghanistan
by
Farid Mamundzay,
Peter Blunt,
Nader Yama, and
Hamidullah Afghan
IDLG Discussion Paper
January 2015
2
Mamundzay, Blunt, Yama & Afghan January, 2015
Summary: It is argued that the battle to restore the sovereignty of the
Afghan state will be won or lost subnationally. Victory will be more likely
if, following Ghani and Lockhart (2008), citizen security can be assured; if
the rule of law can be established and upheld without fear or favour; if
reasonably effective, efficient, merit-based and accountable leadership and
administrative means for service delivery can be institutionalised; and if
social policies can be implemented that cut across regions and ethnic
groups. However, progress towards these ambitious ends and the
introduction in its support of pragmatic, evidence-based policy to
strengthen the existing deconcentrated system of subnational governance
(SNG) is hampered by stakeholder conceptual confusion about SNG,
competing vested interests, and largely incommensurable and irreconcilable
SNG policy paradigms. Success will depend on whether links can be forged
between SNG pragmatic imperatives and political expediency.
‘The crisis of the state in developing countries and the unintended impact
of global aid in weakening those states have undermined their
sovereignty...If global security is dependent on the structural stability of
functioning states, then the global system must, over the medium term,
cohere around the goal of building sovereign states and make it a high
priority’ (Ghani & Lockhart, 2008, p. 169).
‘The most important lines of policy (for the Afghan state) include...
strengthening the foundational legitimacy of the government’ (Rubin, 2013,
p. 440). 1
Introduction
1. The sovereignty and legitimacy2
of any state and the ability of its citizens to
participate in and benefit from the development of national assets depend greatly on how the
geographical pieces of the puzzle that comprise it are managed, jointly and severally.
Subnational governance (SNG) should provide fundamental means for bridging what Ghani
and Lockhart (2008, pp. 3-4) refer to as the ‘sovereignty gap’, or the gap between ‘the de jure
sovereignty that the international system affords such states and their de facto...(inability) to
provide even the most basic services for their citizens’ (parentheses added)
2. We shall argue that this maxim applies with particular force to fragile and war-torn
states like Afghanistan, although difficult to implement because the obstacles to achieving
good governance3
subnationally clearly are more pronounced in conditions of widespread and
chronic conflict and where government institutions at the centre do not work as they should.
In these respects Afghanistan is not an isolated case, being one of the ‘forty to sixty states,
home to nearly two billion people,’ that, according to Ghani and Lockhart (2008, p.1), ‘are
either sliding backward and teetering on the brink of implosion or have already collapsed.’
1
The Carnegie Council describes Rubin as one of the world’s leading experts on Afghanistan, with ‘unmatched’
knowledge of the history of the region, ethnic rivalries and inter-relationships, and ‘insights into the failure of
the state’.
2
Political legitimacy derives from the explicit and implicit recognition by the people of the rights of
governments to govern, which in turn depends on government possessing sufficient authority to do so. Where
governing authorities are not viewed as legitimate, social regulation is more difficult and costly.
3
We consider good governance to be merit-based, effective, equitable, efficient, transparent and accountable
(see, for example, Blunt and Rondinelli, 1997).
3
Mamundzay, Blunt, Yama & Afghan January, 2015
3. Like Ghani and Lockhart (2008), we take the view that the standing-room-only sign in
this development waiting room has been on for far too long - to everyone’s detriment - and
that restitution is well overdue.
4. More so than most, in the case of Afghanistan, we shall show that if there is to be any
chance of state sovereignty redemption the journey towards it must begin with SNG. Our
argument is structured as follows. First, following Ghani and Lockhart (2008), we consider
briefly the ten key functions of a sovereign state. Second, we discuss some of the major
threats to state sovereignty that are evident in Afghanistan and demonstrate why it is that
SNG has a vital role to play in their mitigation. Third, we outline the system of SNG in the
country as it is now and discuss some of the necessary conditions for good policy
development concerning it. Fourth, we analyse the competing paradigms4
of SNG policy that
have evolved and some of the other state-building challenges that Afghanistan’s new
government has to contend with. Fifth, on the basis of political economy and technical
considerations and comparative research, we take a position on what broad form of SNG in
the circumstances makes most sense for the country now and for the foreseeable future. In
doing so, we adopt the widely received contingency approach to such matters (e.g., Blunt &
Jones, 1992), where strategy and structure should depend on contextual factors, including
those suggested by Ghani and Lockhart (2008). And finally, sixth, we consider whether the
logic of our position concerning the preferred character of SNG will be able to withstand the
conflicts of interest and other vicissitudes associated with the different competing policy
paradigms that we identify.
5. The primary (qualitative) data marshalled in support of our arguments were gathered
by the authors via participant observation from May 2014 to January 2015. During this
period, all of the authors either held full-time positions in, or were associated with, the
Independent Directorate for Local Governance (IDLG)5
of the Government of the Islamic
Republic of Afghanistan – one as Deputy Minister (Policy), one as team leader of a
development assistance project, and the others, respectively, as Director and Senior Adviser
of the Strategic Coordination advisory unit within the organisation. The holding of these
positions meant that the authors either instigated or supervised or were intimately involved in,
or privy to, much of the SNG policy discussion and development that took place within IDLG
and in government more generally (see, for example, Independent Directorate for Local
Governance, 2014a, 2014b, and 2014c).
The Notion of Sate Sovereignty
6. It is unusual for a country’s head of state to be someone who possesses scholarly and
professional credentials that are directly related to state governance. This is currently the case
in Afghanistan, where the newly-appointed president, Ashraf Ghani, has a rare combination
of relevant experience – among others, as a professor and senior researcher of anthropology
and political science in the USA, the Netherlands, and Afghanistan, as a minister of finance
in Afghanistan and, for ten years, as chief anthropologist of the World Bank. He was named
among the twenty most influential global thinkers of 2009 and 2010 for his work on fragile
states (Rubin, 2013, p. xix).
4
A paradigm provides theoretical guidelines and sets the standards for legitimate work within the field it
governs. It shapes and directs the ‘puzzle-solving’ activities of the groups of ‘normal scientists’ (Kuhn, 1970)
that work within its confines (Blunt, 1997). Our use of the term ‘policy paradigm’ is analogous to the notion of
‘policy narrative’ (Sutton, 1999) that has become conventional wisdom in development circles.
5
IDLG is the lead central government institution responsible for non-sectoral sub-national government agencies
in Afghanistan. Established by Presidential Decree in 2007, IDLG’s purpose is to ‘oversee’ or ‘monitor’ the
performance of provincial, district and municipal offices. No other government agency has such responsibility.
4
Mamundzay, Blunt, Yama & Afghan January, 2015
7. His most important and most widely cited publication is his book, ‘Fixing Failed
States’ (Ghani & Lockhart, 2008), whose well-constructed arguments deserve to be heard and
to exert a significant influence on policy development under the new government. However,
whether they will be able to withstand unscathed the violent swings and roundabouts of
Afghan politics, and other pressures discussed below, is open to question.
8. The central contention of the book is that the gap between the de jure and de facto
sovereignty of fragile states can only be bridged satisfactorily when governments are able to
perform effectively, and largely unaided, ten core functions. Achieving these ends requires
that the state and those who are providing it with different forms of assistance agree about
what needs to be done, how, why, when and by whom. Importantly, it also requires that the
incentives for the implementing agents of development assistance are structured to promote
the weaning of the state from dependence on external support, which Ghani and Lockhart
(2008) argue is not the case in Afghanistan.
9. The first core function of the sovereign state is to establish the rule of law, ‘the glue
that binds all aspects of the state, the economy and society’ and provides citizens with a clear
and transparent set of rules designed to govern their behaviour and that of other entities
within its boundaries. Without exception, an effective legal system should hold government
and others to account for their actions – whoever they are or whomever they may know -
thereby building public trust and confidence in relevant institutions. In its absence, informal
loci of power and control flourish, resulting in systemic malaise, particularly patronage and
other forms of corruption.
10. The second core function, which is closely related to the first, concerns the state’s
ability to monopolise the legitimate use of violence or force, against both external and
internal threats and those who break the law.
11. The third function - ‘administrative control’ - among other things entails a merit-
based government apparatus and leadership that is accountable within its own structures
(upward accountability) and, crucially, to the citizens that it is meant to serve (downward
accountability). Importantly for our discussion, and reinforcing the contingency approach that
we advocate, such a system observes the principle that ‘when a lower level of government
can handle a particular function, higher levels can stand back to monitor, plan and set the
agenda’ (Ghani & Lockhart, 2008, p. 165). This implies that the delegation of authority to
lower levels within government should be conditional, or contingent upon a range of relevant
technical and non-technical (or political economy) variables.
12. Other core functions of the sovereign state include the sound management of public
finance; investment in education (particularly professional and higher education) and training
and public health; social policies that ‘cut across gender, ethnicity, race, class, spatial location
and religion’; the provision of adequate physical infrastructure to all parts of the country; the
formation of a market economy that is subject to checks and balances and where the roles of
the state and the market are determined according to pragmatic as opposed to ideological
considerations; the sustainable management of state assets in the best interests of all citizens,
particularly natural resources and the protection of the commons (referring in both respects to
the exemplar, Norway); and ‘effective public borrowing’ (Ghani & Lockhart, 2008).
13. As we shall demonstrate below, in fragile states like Afghanistan, good SNG and state
sovereignty go hand-in-hand, in particular, with security, the rule of law, administrative
control, and social policy development and implementation that cuts across geographical and
ethnic boundaries. We argue that the condition of Afghanistan in these and other important
respects should set limits on the character of SNG and the speed of its reform.
5
Mamundzay, Blunt, Yama & Afghan January, 2015
Challenges to State Sovereignty in Afghanistan
14. The task of establishing a well-functioning sovereign state has always been difficult
and expensive in Afghanistan, partly because its geographical position for millennia has
made it subject to geo-politically inspired attention from world powers, which has resulted in
a series of protracted wars; partly because of the incompatible interests, and interference, of
neighbouring states; and partly because of its large size, inhospitable terrain, and complex
ethnic mix. Afghanistan has been, and remains, difficult to govern for the same reasons that it
has been difficult to conquer. So much so that according to Rubin (2002), until the turn of the
century, ‘the national government (was) irrelevant to most people’ and ‘didn’t touch most of
the population’. Matters have improved since then, but not throughout the country, and not
enough to impart significant legitimacy to government at the centre (Rubin, 2013, World
Bank, 2014).
15. The roots of conflict in Afghanistan and its length and intensity make people of all
ethnic groups fearful about the possible disintegration of the country. The decades of war
have been fuelled partly as noted above by the interests of neighbouring states, with whom
regional Afghan commanders have developed close ties, and partly by the geo-political
interests of world powers. One notable effect of this is that the central government in Kabul
has less influence over parts of Afghanistan than do Iran, Pakistan or Uzbekistan. Local
commanders of private militias and insurgent groups who are sponsored by or allied with
these regional powers remain a potent force in the country to this day and are among the
biggest threats to state sovereignty and integrity (Rubin, 2013).
16. Such threats and incursions are piled on top of the infringements of state sovereignty
in Afghanistan brought about by repeated foreign invasions and by the country’s long and
heavy dependence on world powers for military, financial, and development assistance, a
dependence that is as pronounced now as it has ever been. Other ingredients of state
sovereignty, such as investments in people and infrastructure and international relations are
compromised by such dependence.
17. These make ideal storylines for the Taliban and other subversive groups to weave into
a picture of a lackey Afghan state that is incapable of exercising control over its own territory
or providing security and basic services to its people, that is, a state that is sovereign in name
only.
The Year 2014 – the Pressure Mounts
18. The pressures on the Afghan state’s ability to demonstrate otherwise rose sharply in
2014. In a country that for generations has had to contend with far more than its fair share of
cataclysms and sovereignty-threatening events, it may seem disingenuous to suggest that the
year 2014 was an unusual one in terms both of the number and significance of the political
and security challenges encountered by the state. But there are good grounds for making such
a proposition.
19. First, in relation to security, it is estimated that the number of serious insurgency-
related incidents in the country was approximately four times higher in 2014 than it had been
in 2013 - with concomitant increases in civilian casualties (Graham-Harrison, 2014; United
Nations Assistance Mission in Afghanistan, 2014). For an already war-weary citizenry, these
developments cemented security’s place at the top of its list of concerns about the future (The
Asia Foundation, 2014).
20. Unsurprisingly, there is considerable pent-up popular resentment about the suffering
caused by the war, a condition made worse by the fact by the fact that, according to Amnesty
International (2014), there is no institutionalised, credible means in government for
6
Mamundzay, Blunt, Yama & Afghan January, 2015
investigating and reporting publicly on civilian deaths and injuries caused by friendly military
operations. And perpetrators are rarely held to account or pay adequate or any compensation
for their misdeeds. This conveys the impression that they have been granted impunity by
government and its foreign allies, thereby undermining in the eyes of the public important
principles of the rule of law. Bennett (2014) observes that ‘the lack of accountability for
killings of civilians by US/NATO forces in Afghanistan sends a message that foreign troops
have free rein to commit abuses in Afghanistan and that the lives of Afghan civilians have
little or no value’. Published in August 2014, the Amnesty International report examined 10
cases that had caused the deaths of a total of 140 Afghan civilians. None of the cases had
been properly investigated either by foreign or Afghan authorities.
21. The gravity of such incidents for state sovereignty is illustrated by Rubin’s (2013, p.
427) account of the wrongful killing by US troops at a checkpoint of an Afghan boy on a
bicycle. The troops who had shot the boy kept the body for three days (a grave offence in
Islam), while the family waited outside the military camp for its return. ‘After the body was
finally returned, the village elders met and decided to join the Taliban to fight the
Americans.’
22. Second, and equally significant, was the prospect of a new government and the
protracted and acrimonious contest between the two main candidates for president, which
was underlain by interplay between a wide and complex range of patronage, ethnic and
regional vested interests.
23. The delay in the formation of a new government had been caused by allegations of
fraud surrounding the presidential election and tensions between the rivals that had risen
accordingly, to the point of deadlock. Recognising the serious implications of an impasse, the
American Secretary of State, John Kerry, flew to Kabul in July and again in early August
2014 in an attempt to broker an agreement on the basis of an impartial re-assessment of the
validity of all of the votes that had been cast. This helped to break the deadlock and a
government of national unity providing positions at its apex for both candidates – president
and a new position of chief executive - was formally announced in the second half of
September and the new president was inaugurated on 29 September 2014.6
Cabinet positions
were formally announced in mid-January 2015. This constituted the country’s first major
political transition as a nascent democracy.
24. Third was the acceleration of the phased withdrawal of foreign troops and, by the end
of 2014, the assumption by government of complete responsibility for the maintenance of
national security and law and order.
25. Fourth, and simultaneously, management of the state became severely constrained by
significant and sudden reductions in the national budget and in donor funding. These were
seismic changes to an environment of government whose baseline was already extremely
turbulent and unpredictable.
26. The stresses imposed on the state by the military, political and budgetary transitions
were compounded because they were contemporaneous and because transition scheduling
was nearly always driven by internal and external political agendas rather than development
need.
6
As much as anything, breaking the deadlock was important because it prevented the Taliban from being able to
‘claim to have proven that the system of government adopted by Afghans with international support after their
ouster from power cannot function. The increasing capacity of the (Afghan) security forces and the extent of
their international backing (would) be irrelevant if they (had) no legitimate (government) authority to defend’
(parentheses added) (Rubin, 2014).
7
Mamundzay, Blunt, Yama & Afghan January, 2015
27. An optimistic interpretation of the political transition would be to say that it
constituted an unprecedented symbol of progress and of shared interest among the main
power blocs in striving for peace and stability. A less sanguine view would be that the
fundamental points of difference and open antagonism between the parties are unlikely to
dissipate and that they will plague all major decisions, particularly those concerning who will
get what key positions (e.g., provincial governor) and other spoils in government. The
national mood could be said to reflect this in that only a slight majority of 55% of the
population think that the country is moving in the right direction (The Asia Foundation,
2014).
The Year 2015 – a Development Watershed
28. The year 2015 is likely to be a particularly telling one in so far as the battle to restore
state sovereignty in Afghanistan is concerned, one that is dependent upon whether sufficient
security can be maintained for government to establish the rule of law, deliver services and
sustain development, and whether political differences can be set aside – or assuaged
sufficiently - in the interests of state sovereignty and the common good.
29. The main impediment to attaining state sovereignty is the Taliban, who will either
have to be defeated militarily or accommodated and appeased politically. The less likely the
former, the more government will be compelled to consider a political settlement with a
resurgent Taliban, emboldened by the withdrawal of foreign troops and bent on exploiting the
deep political divides in a new and vulnerable government. It seems unlikely that peace and
stability will be attained and sustained without a rapprochement, a move that would likely
receive strong support from Pakistan, a long-term backer of the predominantly Pashtun
Taliban (Harding, 2001). Tomsen (2014), for example, observes that ‘the new Afghan
government…will face long odds in its effort to hold off the Taliban and counter Pakistani
meddling.’
30. The escalation of serious security incidents in the country in 2014 as compared to
2013 and the perpetuation of hostilities and attacks throughout the country during what in the
past has always been the winter off-season mean that the pressure is on government like
never before. Bearing out the plausibility of a rapprochement scenario, by January 2015, the
international news media were reporting that talks with the Taliban had begun, but that offers
of positions in the new government had been rejected by them (Loyn, 2015), suggesting that
they will not be bought-off easily.
31. Fundamental differences concerning the constitution and the bases of the legitimacy
of the state and the position of women in society are some of the main stumbling blocks in
negotiations (e.g., Kane, 2015). Even so, some suggest that despite these obstacles and its
reliance on ‘on strongmen, manipulation, and patronage networks’, the Taliban may be
shifting its ground politically, towards Afghan mainstream politics. For its part, mainstream
politics is said to be ‘becoming more violent and ruthless and in a sense...moving closer to
the Taliban’s way of doing things’ (Giustozzi & Mangal, 2015), perhaps indicating that both
sides are keen to do business and that the Taliban recognise the importance of establishing
political legitimacy.
32. These events and prospects bring to an already traumatised nation heightened
uncertainty, conflict and stress and they raise considerably the likelihood and stakes of
government failure.
33. One effect of these conditions should be to increase the importance that government
attaches to those few levers of state sovereignty influence over which it has some measure of
direct control. As noted above, these include what Ghani et al. (2006) and Ghani and Lockhart
8
Mamundzay, Blunt, Yama & Afghan January, 2015
(2008) refer to as ‘administrative control’, ‘delineation of state and citizen rights and duties’,
‘monopoly of the means of violence’, and the establishment of the rule of law. Ghani et al.
(2006, p. 7) describe the interplay between some of these factors in terms of:
‘...both the breadth and depth of the reach of a state’s authority over its territory...In order
to establish and maintain administrative control, a state requires the following: the
existence of a coherent set of rules that determine the division of responsibilities
horizontally and vertically across functions of the state and between hierarchical levels;
the recruitment of civil servants; the spatial and functional division of administrative
roles; and flows of resources. The extent to which the citizens of a state accept that the
promulgation and enforcement of these rules serves the interest of the majority is crucial
to engendering trust between the state and its citizens and giving citizens a sense of
belonging. The structure of administration could vary in practice between highly
centralized to highly federated depending on the historical and cultural context’.
The Importance of SNG to State Sovereignty
34. In the general sense just described, but particularly in the other respects mentioned
above and below, the form and quality of SNG is clearly vital to state sovereignty and
legitimacy in Afghanistan.
35. The new government’s recognition of the importance of this link is evident in the
‘Realising Self-Reliance’ document it presented to the London Conference in December,
2014, where it made clear its intention to review (2010) sub-national policy in order ‘to
provide greater clarity on the roles and responsibilities of sub-national officials’ and to create
governance circumstances that enable ‘people across all provinces (to) have greater voice.’
(Government of the Islamic Republic of Afghanistan, 2014, p.12). These policy intentions
target questions of upward and downward accountability, which are of critical significance to
the establishment of state sovereignty, a maxim emphasised throughout Ghani and Lockhart
(2008) and by others like Bene and Neiland (2006) and IDLG (2014c).
36. The wait-and-see nature of the national mood on questions of governance provides
government with an opportunity to demonstrate its credentials in these and other important
respects, but as we have shown popular patience is – and has been - under severe strain,
limiting the time available for government to be seen to be doing the right things.
Strengthening those drivers of state sovereignty that are integral to SNG will be central to
this, as confirmed by the latest survey results, which show that at the local level, apart from
security, the main problems reported by citizens have to do with electricity, roads, drinking
water, education, and healthcare (The Asia Foundation, 2014).
Necessary Conditions: Conceptual Clarity and Altruism
37. To begin to address these issues coherently and constructively, ideally all stakeholders
should be clear about the main features of the different forms of SNG that are available, or
what the options are (e.g., World Bank Institute, 1999; IDLG, 2014c), and their intentions
should be genuinely altruistic and aligned. However, as elsewhere, policy discourse
surrounding SNG in Afghanistan does not enjoy these advantages, albeit that among some of
the parties involved, there is recognition of the need for conceptual clarity, which has resulted
in steps being taken towards establishing this necessary condition (e.g., Adam Smith
International, 2014, 2015).
38. Such clarity should begin with agreement concerning the nature of the existing system
of subnational governance in Afghanistan, which can be characterised as being
deconcentrated but with limited elements of political, fiscal, and market decentralisation.
9
Mamundzay, Blunt, Yama & Afghan January, 2015
Services are delivered subnationally by geographically dispersed units or offices of line
ministries and are controlled from the centre - although, as in any organisational structure,
varying degrees of delegation of authority and responsibility are possible within the system.
Political decentralisation manifests itself in the form of elected provincial councils, which are
the main means of downward accountability. But the roles and functions and authorities of
the councils, and of councillors, are ill-defined in existing legislation. The same is true of the
crucial positions of provincial and district governor, whose formal authorities are limited and
poorly defined (reducing upward accountability), but who wield enormous informal power
and thereby pose a significant challenge to the legitimacy of government at the centre.
39. Below, we shall refer to the existing system of SNG in Afghanistan as being
‘deconcentrated’, but this remains a term that is perhaps not as widely understood to
comprise what we have just suggested as it might be.
40. The second condition – comprising altruism and alignment, in the sense described by
Ghani and Lockhart (2008) – is more problematic, because of the variety of interests
represented among both internal and external actors. Despite rhetorical claims to the contrary,
these interests are incommensurable and therefore largely irreconcilable and levels of
altruism are variable (e.g., Chang, 2002, 2009).
41. We would expect state sovereignty not to fare very well under these circumstances –
according to some, state compliance being a much more sought after quality in the
development partners of rich countries (e.g., Chang, 2002, 2009; Chomsky, 2010; Roy,
2004). Ghani and Lockhart (2008) reach somewhat similar conclusions:
‘The central task that the aid system should perform—namely, generating prosperity by
bringing a global knowledge of stocks and flows to countries without it—is not being
performed. In view of the fact that it comprises extractive industries and technical
assistance brigades, the aid system—instead of opening countries up to legitimate
entrepreneurial activity—epitomizes the side of capitalism that is fundamentally
exploitative’ (p. 86).
42. For these reasons and others that we shall examine below, achieving policy discourse
coherence on SNG in Afghanistan, as elsewhere, is likely to be less than straightforward.
The Democracy Promotion Paradigm
43. When it comes to the distribution of power subnationally, among local actors,
Tomsen’s (2014) observations on the subject of SNG suggest that the two main Afghan
schools of thought are not that far apart. The more radical of the two is said to be prepared to
countenance devolution of limited authority to ‘elected provincial and district governors’,
while the ‘others believe that the status quo, with power rigidly centralised in Kabul, will
remain necessary as long as the insurgency continues’.
44. Tomsen’s account and his use of words like ‘rigidly’ imply that he subscribes to the
ideologically-inspired conventional wisdom of much of the donor community, a view that
sees extreme forms of decentralisation as being the end point of a virtuous natural
progression that begins with central control. In contrast, we take the view that this policy
paradigm confuses means and ends. It does so by assuming that a particular means of SNG
(decentralisation) is a desirable end in itself, based largely on ideological convictions
associated with ‘democracy promotion’. It ignores the substantial body of research evidence
that shows what limited success - in terms of development ends like poverty and inequality
reduction - decentralisation has enjoyed in developing countries, but particularly in fragile
states (Blunt & Turner, 2005, 2007). Rubin (2013, p. 122) agrees: ‘The international
10
Mamundzay, Blunt, Yama & Afghan January, 2015
community involved in assisting Afghanistan in such matters pays lip service to the agenda of
strengthening the central government but works pragmatically with a variety of regional
forces, reinforcing fragmentation. Global trends that see decentralisation as conducive to
democracy and grassroots development legitimate such decisions.’
45. As, for example, in Cambodia, we suggest below that at least some national
politicians are likely to see things very differently, perhaps regarding democracy promotion
per se as having little value, except as rhetorical window dressing (Blunt & Turner, 2005).
Political Expediency Paradigms
46. The vision statements or election manifestos of the new president and the chief
executive suggest that they disagree on matters that affect SNG, although it is still not yet
clear where the two main power blocs in government stand on this issue. Disagreement
between them seems likely for the reasons that we have already given, but the question is by
how much and with what implications for SNG? Rubin (2014), for example, observes that
they have different views about ‘the degree of centralisation of the state; the balance of power
between regional, ethnic, and tribal coalitions; control over the security forces; the role of the
former armed resistance, and how all of these will affect the distribution of the diminishing
flows of foreign aid’.
47. Taken at face value, these are clearly important areas of potential difference. But even
in the best of circumstances we know that political election platforms and promises are
unreliable guides to policy enactment by elected governments. Politicians everywhere are
notorious for saying one thing during elections and doing something quite different once they
are in office. The correlation between political rhetoric and policy reality is noted more for its
weakness than strength (Blunt, 2009, p. 94).
48. In relation to ‘the degree of centralisation of the state’, we argue below that there are
good reasons for supposing that, despite what may have been said by each side, in some
fundamental respects it is unlikely that there will be marked divergences between them on
this matter, and that this makes good sense.
49. We say this because it seems probable that, when it comes to making decisions about
SNG, the nature of informal power relations between the centre and the periphery, and among
different entities at the periphery, which have been problematic in Afghanistan historically
(Rubin, 2002, 2013), are likely to be of paramount concern to both parties. To the extent that
some measure of control cannot be exercised over sub-national powerbrokers,7
the state will
be significantly weakened and could fail altogether. That is to say, the multiplicity of sites of
informal power outside of Kabul (warlords and some governors) that continue to contest
control over territory and other key resources among themselves and with the centre, and
openly to flout its authority, threaten to fragment the state and to make it ungovernable
(though local power brokers seem not, as in some other countries, to be interested in
secession). This conclusion is supported by Turner (2006, p. 1), who states that, in
Afghanistan, ‘Intra-state instability is the dominant pattern which needs to be overcome.’
50. In support of our conjecture, both sides are said by Rubin (2013, p. 440) to recognise
that devolution or ‘the decentralisation of service provision’ is not just a technical matter, and
that it could inflame ‘the most potentially divisive issue, namely the relation of the state to
different ethnic groups and in particular to Pashtuns and non-Pashtuns’.
7
How this is done will need to take account of the dynamics of such local power relations, rather than to rely
solely or largely on capacity building or attempt to overwhelm them by force (Lister, 2007; Mukhopadhyay,
2009).
11
Mamundzay, Blunt, Yama & Afghan January, 2015
51. This makes it unlikely that either side in the new government will want to move
quickly – or, for the time being, perhaps at all - towards ceding greater formal power to the
periphery, that is, to move away from the current system of deconcentration towards a more
devolved system of SNG. This is not to say, however, that the two sides would necessarily
agree about how the current system of deconcentrated SNG should be strengthened and
developed – for example, differences of opinion are likely to emerge when it comes to the
distribution of authority and resources within it and in relation to procedures governing the
appointment and removal of governors (the potential for disagreement concerning the latter is
illustrated in IDLG, 2014a).
Contingency-based Paradigm
52. If we are to take seriously the view expressed by Ghani and Lockhart (2008, p. 199) -
that ‘tailoring to context’ should be ‘a key attribute of national programs’ – then we submit
that the circumstances of the country discussed so far and other considerations set out below
make this an optimal strategy for the new government to pursue.
53. Somewhat paradoxically, perhaps, in the short to medium terms this will mean that in
order to make government more relevant to the scattered and diverse population that occupies
Afghanistan’s vast geographical space, it will be necessary first to establish effective and
legitimate government at the centre (Rubin, 2007, 2013).
54. The main reconstruction task in Afghanistan should therefore be the accommodation
and control of regionally-based (informal) powers by a central power that has the capacity to
deliver basic services of reasonable quality throughout the country and to perform the other
tasks of a sovereign state that we have outlined, a goal that for the most part is still far from
being achieved. This view is endorsed by Blunt and Turner (2007, p. 120) in their assessment
of research evidence from a number of conflict and post conflict states: ‘Deconcentration is
particularly relevant for weak or fragile states as it can be seen as a method of increasing the
strength of the state to provide its citizens with the services they are entitled to....a strong
foundation of prior centralization is a necessary basis for successful political decentralisation.
Deconcentration can be seen as a step in this direction.’
55. Support for this conclusion can also be found in Rubin’s research, which over many
years has shown that among ordinary Afghans ‘there is a universally expressed preference for
being governed by a central authority that obeys some laws and where a district governor can
be changed by the central government if he or she didn’t do the right thing’ (Rubin, 2002). As
they did then, most people now want to get rid of the ‘rule of the gun’ and regard a strong
central government as being the principal means of achieving this. In 2002, Rubin observed
that Afghans wanted this because they ‘associate local control with control by gunmen and
warlords’, a situation that in many parts of the country is likely to have become a lot worse.
Ten years later, in 2013, his views on the subject are largely unchanged, although qualified
by the observation that continuing popular support for centralisation would depend very
much on how it was implemented, noting that increasingly many Afghans want to be
‘participating citizens’ as opposed to ‘passive subjects’ (Rubin, 2013, pp. 130-131).
Challenges and Consequences of Failure
56. The challenges of strengthening government at the centre are likely to be much the
same now as they were in 2007 when Rubin observed that important central institutions are
‘deeply corrupt and plagued by a lack of basic skills, equipment and resources. Without
effective and honest administrators, police, and judges, the state can do little to provide
internal security – and if the government does not provide security, people will not recognise
12
Mamundzay, Blunt, Yama & Afghan January, 2015
it as a government’. Everyone knows that there is much still to do in all of these respects, and
that the deep funding cuts that are in prospect will make everything more difficult. These
challenges are more pronounced at the periphery.
57. Yet, while more difficult, the importance of making real and rapid progress in these
respects is greater now than ever before. And the consequences of failing in this endeavour
are not difficult to imagine, among them a descent ‘into a full-scale civil war’ (Tomsen,
2014) or ‘a slide into chaos when the Americans leave and the Afghan army is pushed into a
“fortress Kabul” strategy, as the Taliban re-take the countryside, worsening ethnic conflict,
and neighbouring states arm their Afghan proxies, and a refugee crisis ensues as millions of
Afghans again flee the country’ (Rashid, 2013). It is clearly not in the interests of western
powers, of either of the two main figures in government or of the Kabul political elite in
general for any of these things to happen. As Rubin (2014) points out, all of the parties want
to win, ‘but they know that they could all lose.’
Pragmatic Imperatives of SNG
‘Once Afghanistan no longer fears for its own disintegration, it will become more
feasible for the state to experiment with forms of local governance and
decentralisation...in order to provide the services that the Afghan people are now
demanding’ (Rubin, 2013, p. 441).
58. Against this background, when it comes to the distribution of power and resources in
government subnationally, the rationality of keeping things more or less as they are (for now
and the foreseeable future) and trying to make them work better has a firm basis in national
and sub-national political economy, in the unpalatability to western powers and to both sides
in government and the Kabul political and business establishment of a return to chaos and,
most importantly, in popular preferences.
59. This position, which relies on the contingency-based paradigm, is reinforced by a
number of other considerations. First, it is well-established in the research literature that
where government institutions at the centre are weak and patronage is systemic devolving
power and resources to local governments simply provides sustenance for the spread of
patronage to the periphery and its entrenchment (e.g., Blunt et al., 2012a, 2012b). In his
discussion of governance in Afghanistan, Rubin (2002) expresses the same view when he
says that ‘international experience with devolution/decentralisation is that if you try it in a
rather chaotic situation without a strong legal system, it is a formula for corruption rather than
effective self-government’. The classic statement of this position is Diamond (1999): ‘Where
hierarchical chains of particularistic, patron–client relationships are already the dominant
mode of politics, shifting discretionary financial authority from the central to the local level
may simply shift the locus of clientelism and corruption from the central to the local arena,
making these problems even tougher to control’ (p. 244).
60. Second, as elsewhere, significant change towards decentralised government in
Afghanistan would require additional human and financial resources, and would lead
inevitably to bureaucratic inflation, at a time when government revenues and donor funding
are in steep decline and government capacity sub-nationally is weak and is likely to remain so
for some time to come - as Rubin (2013, p. 440) confirms: ‘the (Afghan) state is simply too
weak to manage decentralised service provision.’ Again, this is a conclusion that is well
supported by comparative research: ‘is it wise in circumstances where central governance
institutions are widely recognised as being weak...to embark on a difficult and costly
devolution programme? Would scarce development resources be better spent initially on
strengthening these core institutions – the legal and judicial systems for example – or on
13
Mamundzay, Blunt, Yama & Afghan January, 2015
supporting existing systems of deconcentration that are the only existing means of (weak)
service delivery in crucial sectors such as health, education, and agriculture?’(Blunt &
Turner, 2007, p. 122).
61. Third, in any case, the evidence shows that more often than not devolved systems of
SNG fail to deliver in practice what they promise in theory, and that the chances of success
are sharply reduced where governance institutions at the centre are weak. In support of this
conclusion, recent research on these issues sponsored by the World Bank concludes that
decentralisation or ‘participation... appears to affect the distribution of benefits in ways that
suggest that capture is often not “benevolent” or altruistic’ (Mansuri & Rao, 2013, p. 6).
62. A similar conclusion is reached by Blunt and Turner (2007, p. 127):
‘Experience has shown how even the best-intentioned experiment in democratic
devolution can fail to live up to expectations and in some instances can leave people,
especially the poor and disadvantaged, worse off than before. Yet, despite weak central
institutions of governance and high cost, development practice nearly always eschews
deconcentration in favour of democratic decentralisation although this latter label is
frequently in name only.’
63. And, most tellingly, fourth, there is considerable evidence from conflict and post-
conflict states to suggest that more devolved systems of SNG can lead to the intensification
of inter-regional and inter-ethnic conflict (Schou & Haug, 2005).
64. Accordingly, we submit that the short to medium term task in Afghanistan should be
to construct a state structure that is strong enough at the centre to unite the country, provide
security, and establish the rule of law and, within the existing system of deconcentration,
allows enough authority to permeate to lower levels in the provinces to give citizens – who,
according to Rubin (2013), ‘are politicised as never before’ – the opportunity to exercise
some influence on policies and practices that affect their lives.
Conclusion
‘A weak state results when internal and external actors prove themselves
incapable of aligning around the goal of sovereignty’ (Ghani & Lockhart,
2008, p. 177).
65. Our discussion of the necessary conditions for coherent SNG policy discourse in
Afghanistan and of the three main SNG policy paradigms suggests that aligning external and
internal actors around the goal of state sovereignty – and, hence, bridging the sovereignty gap
- will be far from straight forward. Of the two necessary conditions, achieving conceptual
clarity is feasible, but reconciling competing vested interests and ensuring undiluted or
uniform altruism seem to us to be much less so. This suggests that it may not be just a
question of incapability among stakeholders that inhibits alignment around the goal of state
sovereignty, but also – and more importantly - their willingness to do so.
66. These shaky foundations underlie SNG policy paradigms that for the most part in any
case are incommensurable and irreconcilable. The democracy promotion paradigm of SNG is
ideologically-driven and therefore - as a matter of faith – unlikely to be amenable to rational
argument. Its principal interest is to promote ‘democracy’ and decentralisation come what
may, that is, irrespective of what the evidence might suggest will be the benefits for ordinary
people or for state sovereignty. Paradigm failures, which in any event may not be measured
in the above terms, can always be rationalised or written-off as a function of some
combination of recalcitrant and corrupt local officials, a lack of political will, and insufficient
14
Mamundzay, Blunt, Yama & Afghan January, 2015
capacity, that is, as the fault of the victim. These conditions are unlikely to be peculiar to
Afghanistan (e.g., Blunt, 2014).
67. The political expediency paradigms, on the other hand, are supremely pragmatic but
only in so far as certain categories of evidence are concerned. It is here we believe that the
best prospects lie for acceptance of the pragmatic imperatives that we advocate as a basis for
strengthening and maintaining for the foreseeable future the current system of deconcentrated
SNG in Afghanistan.
68. Making it clear that over-ambitious and premature devolution is likely to increase
significantly political risk and constrain progress towards state sovereignty is the key to
producing SNG policy that is optimal for equitable and sustainable development. If
decentralising government and ceding greater formal authority to governors, some of whom
already openly flout the authority of the state, will undermine the rule of law; if it will
intensify inter-ethnic and inter-regional conflict that is already at a high pitch; if it will make
security in those parts of the country controlled or threatened by the Taliban and other
insurgent groups more difficult to attain; if, because service provision is unlikely to be
improved, it will undermine the legitimacy of government at the centre; if it will increase the
financial burden on government without providing any certainty of increased fiscal return or
improved service delivery; if it will direct scarce investment away from ‘human capital’ and
physical infrastructure; and if it will limit the ability of government to introduce social
policies that benefit all regions and ethnic groups more or less equally. Then, for all of these
reasons and because, as we noted earlier, all political interests want to win but they also
realise that they could all lose, politics and pragmatism could coalesce around maintaining
and strengthening the existing deconcentrated system of SNG.
69. But despite the evident weight of political and pragmatic argument in its favour, this
happy conclusion is far from being a policy slam dunk. As with policy development
everywhere, resistance, serendipity, opportunism, and irrationality will all come in to play
(Sutton, 1999), and could tilt the balance against an optimal development or state sovereignty
outcome. It remains to be seen whether government can resist these pressures and achieve
policy discourse leadership or dominance in the interests of state sovereignty and the
common good.
70. All stakeholders have vital roles to play in this. Clearly, the more that development
assistance and different arms of government can align themselves with the president’s vision
of state sovereignty the better. We have shown here the strong links that exist between SNG
and important aspects of state sovereignty, providing clear direction for all of those who want
to see Afghanistan standing on its own feet as soon as possible, direction that should help to
make development assistance more cost-effective because it will be more likely to succeed.
And if, as Ghani and Lockhart (2008) suggest in our opening quote, genuinely sovereign
states are the building blocks of a secure, stable and peaceful global order then striving for
and supporting state sovereignty in Afghanistan could have much wider implications.
71. It should be stressed, however, that the vision of alignment expressed by the president
and outlined here is not simply donor coordination by another name. As we have shown, the
president’s vision of state sovereignty is explicit about the necessity for national leadership
and it is equally explicit about what in broad terms will need to be done.
72. Each stakeholder is likely to face different constraints in conforming to these
imperatives. However, the job of reconciling such constraints with the national interest will
be made easier if donors and other stakeholders can adopt the contingency-based approach to
programme design and policy development advocated by the president and in this paper.
15
Mamundzay, Blunt, Yama & Afghan January, 2015
73. IDLG, for example, has adopted this approach in relation to forming a view about the
preferred character of SNG, and herein has demonstrated the links between policy in favour
of strengthening the existing system of deconcentration and state sovereignty. It is incumbent
upon other government and non-government stakeholders to do the same with respect to their
own areas of responsibility.
References
Adam Smith International (2014). Briefing Note on SNG Terminology. Kabul, December,
mimeo, pp. 5.
Adam Smith International (2015). Policy Discussion Paper: Subnational Governance and
State Sovereignty. Kabul: January, mimeo, pp. 12
Amnesty International (2014). Left in the Dark: Failures of Accountability for Civilian
Casualties Caused by International Military Operations in Afghanistan. August,
London: Peter Benson House. Retrieved on 24 September, 2014 from:
http://www.amnesty.org/en/library/asset/asa11/006/2014/en/c628b1a4-821f-4168-a583-
ac4a6159986e/asa110062014en.pdf
Bene, C. & Neiland, A.E. (2006). From Participation to Governance. Institute for the
Sustainable Development of Fisheries: Portsmouth, UK.
Bennett, R. (2014). Afghanistan: Urgent Enquiry Needed after New US Airstrike Increases
Civilian Death Toll. Afghanistan Times, 14 September, p. 6.
Blunt, P. (1997). Prisoners of the Paradigm: Process Consultants and ‘Clinical’ Development
Practitioners. Public Administration and Development, 17: 341-349.
Blunt, P. (2009). The Political Economy of Accountability in Timor Leste: Implications for
Public Policy. Public Administration and Development, 29: 89-100.
Blunt, P. (2014). Whose Resources are they anyway? Community Development Agreements
in the Mongolian Mining Sector. Progress in Development Studies, 14(4): 383-399.
Blunt, P., and Jones, M. (1992). Managing Organisations in Africa. Berlin & New York:
Walter de Gruyter, pp. 356 & xiv.
Blunt, P., and Rondinelli, D. (1997). Reconceptualising Governance. New York:
Management Development and Governance Division, UNDP, Discussion Paper
Number 2.
Blunt, P., and Turner, M. (2005). Decentralisation, Democracy and Development in a Post-
Conflict State: Commune Councils in Cambodia. Public Administration and
Development, 25 (1): 75-87.
Blunt, P., and Turner, M. (2007). Decentralisation, Deconcentration and Poverty Reduction in
the Asia Pacific. In S. Cheema & D. Rondinelli (Eds.), Decentralized Governance:
Emerging Concepts and Practices. Cambridge, Mass.: Brookings Institution Press and
the Ash Institute for Democratic Governance and Innovation, John F.K. Kennedy
School of Government, Harvard University, pp. 115-130.
Blunt, P., Turner, M., and Lindroth, H. (2012a). Patronage, Service Delivery and Social
Justice in Indonesia. International Journal of Public Administration, 35(3): 214-220.
Blunt, P., Turner, M., and Lindroth, H. (2012b). Patronage’s Progress in Post-Soeharto
Indonesia. Public Administration and Development, 32(1): 64-81.
Chang, Ha-Joon. (2002). Kicking Away the Ladder: Development Strategy in Historical
Perspective. London: Anthem Press.
Chang, Ha-Joon. (2009). Bad Samaritans. New York: Bloomsbury Press.
Chomsky, N. (2010). Hopes and prospects. London: Penguin.
Diamond, L. (1999). Developing Democracy: Towards Consolidation. Baltimore: Johns
Hopkins University Press.
16
Mamundzay, Blunt, Yama & Afghan January, 2015
Ghani, A., Lockhart, C., and Carnahan, M. (2006). Closing the Sovereignty Gap: an
Approach to State-Building. London: Overseas Development Institute, Working Paper
253. Retrieved on 16 December, 2014 from:
http://www.odi.org/sites/odi.org.uk/files/odi-assets/publications-opinion-
files/2482.pdf
Giustozzi, A., & Mangal, S. (2015). Violence, the Taliban and Afghanistan’s 2014 Elections.
United States Institute of Peace, 7 January. Retrieved on 16 January, 2015 from:
http://www.usip.org/publications/violence-the-taliban-and-afghanistan-s-2014-
elections
Ghani, A., & Lockhart, C. (2008). Fixing Failed States: A Framework for Rebuilding a
Fractured World. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Government of the Islamic Republic of Afghanistan (2014). Realising Self-Reliance:
Commitments to Reforms and Renewed Partnership. December, Kabul & London,
London Conference on Afghanistan, mimeo, pp. 24.
Graham-Harrison, E. (2014). Afghanistan's war takes heavy civilian toll, says United Nations
report. The Guardian, 9 July. Retrieved on 3 October, 2014 from:
http://www.theguardian.com/world/2014/jul/09/afghanistan-war-civilian-toll-united-
nations-report
Harding, L. (2001). Taliban Moderates Offered Future Role: Powell Backs Call to Afghan
Pragmatists. The Guardian, 17 October. Retrieved on 16 January, 2015 from:
http://www.theguardian.com/world/2001/oct/17/pakistan.afghanistan
IDLG (2014a). Procedures for the Recruitment, Selection, Appointment, and Removal of
Provincial Governors. September, Kabul: IDLG Policy Brief, pp. 7.
IDLG (2014b). IDLG Strategy, Structure, and Functions: Adjusting to Conditions of
Environmental Hostility and Complexity. Kabul: IDLG Discussion Paper, pp. 17.
IDLG (2014c). Enhancing IDLG’s Contributions to national and Sub-National Governance:
Rationale, Strategic Opportunities, and Reform Proposals. October, Kabul: IDLG
Strategic Review – Discussion Paper, pp.49.
Kane, S. (2015). Talking with the Taliban: Should the Constitution be a Point of Negotiation?
Unites States Institute of Peace, 12 January. Retrieved on 16 January, 2015 from:
http://www.usip.org/publications/talking-the-taliban-should-the-afghan-constitution-
be-point-of-negotiation
Kuhn, T. S. (1970). ‘Logic of discovery or psychology of research?’ in Lakatos I., and
Musgrave A. (eds.), Criticism and the Growth of Knowledge. London: Cambridge
University Press.
Lister, S. (2007). Understanding State-Building and Local Government in Afghanistan.
London: London School of Economics, Crisis States Research Centre, Working Paper
no. 14. Retrieved on 28 August, 2014 from:
http://www.lse.ac.uk/internationalDevelopment/research/crisisStates/download/wp/w
pSeries2/wp142.pdf
Loyn, D. (2015). Taliban ‘Reject Offer of Afghan Government Posts’. BBC News Asia.
Retrieved on 14 January, 2015 from: http://www.bbc.com/news/world-asia-30737664
Mansuri, G. & Rao V. (2013). Localising Development: Does Participation Work?
Washington DC: World Bank.
Mukhopadhyay, D. (2009). Warlords as Bureaucrats: the Afghan Experience. Washington
DC: Carnegie Endowment for International Peace, Carnegie Papers, Middle East
Programme, Number 101. Retrieved on 27 August, 2014 from:
http://carnegieendowment.org/files/warlords_as_bureaucrats.pdf
17
Mamundzay, Blunt, Yama & Afghan January, 2015
Rashid, Ahmed. (2013). Afghanistan after the War: Is Peace Possible. New Republic, 28
March. Retrieved on 8 August, 2014 from:
http://www.newrepublic.com/article/112680/afghanistan-after-war
Roy, A. (2004). An Ordinary Person’s Guide to Empire. Cambridge, Mass.: Southend Press.
Rubin, B. (2002). The Fragmentation of Afghanistan: State Formation and Collapse in the
International System. Talk delivered to the Carnegie Council, 25 June, 2002.
Retrieved on 3 August, 2014 from:
http://www.carnegiecouncil.org/studio/multimedia/20020625/index.html
Rubin, B. (2007). Saving Afghanistan. Foreign Affairs, January/February. Retrieved on 16
August, 2014 from: http://www.foreignaffairs.com/articles/62270/barnett-r-
rubin/saving-afghanistan
Rubin, B. (2013). Afghanistan from the Cold War through the War on Terror. Oxford:
Oxford University Press.
Rubin, B. (2014). The Election is the Enemy. Foreign Policy, 2 April. Retrieved on 13
August, 2014 from:
http://www.foreignpolicy.com/articles/2014/04/02/afghanistan_elections_taliban_gha
ni_attacks
Schou, A., & Haug, M. (2005). Decentralisation in Conflict and Post-Conflict Situations.
Oslo: Norwegian Institute for Urban and Regional Research, Working Paper 139.
Retrieved on 31 October, 2014 from: http://www.nibr.no/filer/2005-139.pdf
Sutton, R. (1999). The Policy Process: An Overview. London: Overseas Development
Institute, mimeo, pp. 35.
The Asia Foundation (2014). Afghanistan in 2014: a Survey of the Afghan People. Kabul:
The Asia Foundation, pp. 251. Retrieved on 9 December, 2014 from:
http://www.asiafoundation.org/publications/pdf/1425
Tomsen, P. (2014). The Good War? What went wrong in Afghanistan and How to make it
Right. Foreign Affairs, 93(6).
Transparency International (2014). Corruption Perception Index 2013. Retrieved on 7
August, 2014 from: http://www.transparency.org/cpi2013/results
Turner, M. (2006). State Consolidation and Subnational Governance in Afghanistan, Paper
presented at International Research Symposium on Public Management 10
(IRSPMX), Glasgow Caledonian University, 10-12 April.
United Nations Assistance Mission in Afghanistan (2014). 2014 Sees Highest Civilian
Casualty Figures Recorded. New York, 19 December. Retrieved on 20 December,
2014 from:
http://unama.unmissions.org/Default.aspx?tabid=12254&ctl=Details&mid=15756&It
emID=38492&language=en-US
World Bank (2014). Critical Administrative Constraints to Service Delivery: Improving
Public Services in Afghanistan’s Transformational Decade. Kabul: World Bank, pp.
133.
World Bank Institute. (1999). Decentralisation Briefing Notes. Retrieved on 18 August, 2014
from: http://siteresources.worldbank.org/WBI/Resources/wbi37142.pdf

More Related Content

What's hot

Japanese Diet - Parliamentary Committee Oversight
Japanese Diet - Parliamentary Committee Oversight Japanese Diet - Parliamentary Committee Oversight
Japanese Diet - Parliamentary Committee Oversight
John David Garrett
 
Transition and Good Governance_FINAL_DRAFT3
Transition and Good Governance_FINAL_DRAFT3Transition and Good Governance_FINAL_DRAFT3
Transition and Good Governance_FINAL_DRAFT3
Yama Nader
 
India Legal 15 February 2016
India Legal 15 February 2016 India Legal 15 February 2016
India Legal 15 February 2016
ENC
 
Accountability and transparency in legislative process in nigeria a challenge
Accountability and transparency in legislative process in nigeria a challengeAccountability and transparency in legislative process in nigeria a challenge
Accountability and transparency in legislative process in nigeria a challenge
Alexander Decker
 
Governance crisis
Governance crisisGovernance crisis
Governance crisis
knowledge1995
 
14-09-09-NR Advisory Note 1
14-09-09-NR Advisory Note 114-09-09-NR Advisory Note 1
14-09-09-NR Advisory Note 1
Scott Carlson
 
India legal 31 january 2016
India legal 31 january 2016 India legal 31 january 2016
India legal 31 january 2016
ENC
 
Handbook on security sector governance.5
Handbook on security sector governance.5Handbook on security sector governance.5
Handbook on security sector governance.5
Kayode Fayemi
 
Executive legislative relation in ghana
Executive legislative  relation in ghanaExecutive legislative  relation in ghana
Executive legislative relation in ghana
ernestboadi
 
National security doctrine
National security doctrineNational security doctrine
National security doctrine
Col Mukteshwar Prasad
 
Bad Governance
Bad Governance Bad Governance
Bad Governance
Stephen Hernon
 
Democratic oversight of the security sector the nigerian experience
Democratic oversight of the security sector   the nigerian experienceDemocratic oversight of the security sector   the nigerian experience
Democratic oversight of the security sector the nigerian experience
Kayode Fayemi
 
Decentralization and corruption in afghanistan
Decentralization and corruption in afghanistanDecentralization and corruption in afghanistan
Decentralization and corruption in afghanistan
Palwasha Meranzai
 
Handbook on security sector governance.3
Handbook on security sector governance.3Handbook on security sector governance.3
Handbook on security sector governance.3
Kayode Fayemi
 
Good governance: A matter of choice or compulsion for the developing nations
Good governance: A matter of choice or compulsion for the developing nationsGood governance: A matter of choice or compulsion for the developing nations
Good governance: A matter of choice or compulsion for the developing nations
Muhammad Asif Khan
 
Federalsim and restructuring in nigeria
Federalsim and restructuring in nigeriaFederalsim and restructuring in nigeria
Federalsim and restructuring in nigeria
nellyvin1
 
Party politics and democratic governance in nigerian local
Party politics and democratic governance in nigerian localParty politics and democratic governance in nigerian local
Party politics and democratic governance in nigerian local
Alexander Decker
 
Good governance module, Bishkek Academy, 2018
Good governance module, Bishkek Academy, 2018Good governance module, Bishkek Academy, 2018
Good governance module, Bishkek Academy, 2018
Murod Khusanov
 
OVERSIGHT FUNCTIONS OF NIGERIA'S NATIONAL ASSEMBLY; 2011 - 2015
OVERSIGHT FUNCTIONS OF NIGERIA'S NATIONAL ASSEMBLY; 2011 - 2015 OVERSIGHT FUNCTIONS OF NIGERIA'S NATIONAL ASSEMBLY; 2011 - 2015
OVERSIGHT FUNCTIONS OF NIGERIA'S NATIONAL ASSEMBLY; 2011 - 2015
Yagana Bintube (MNIM)
 
Raymond Atuguba on why we must eat the Ghana Constitution
Raymond Atuguba on why we must eat the Ghana ConstitutionRaymond Atuguba on why we must eat the Ghana Constitution
Raymond Atuguba on why we must eat the Ghana Constitution
Amos Anyimadu
 

What's hot (20)

Japanese Diet - Parliamentary Committee Oversight
Japanese Diet - Parliamentary Committee Oversight Japanese Diet - Parliamentary Committee Oversight
Japanese Diet - Parliamentary Committee Oversight
 
Transition and Good Governance_FINAL_DRAFT3
Transition and Good Governance_FINAL_DRAFT3Transition and Good Governance_FINAL_DRAFT3
Transition and Good Governance_FINAL_DRAFT3
 
India Legal 15 February 2016
India Legal 15 February 2016 India Legal 15 February 2016
India Legal 15 February 2016
 
Accountability and transparency in legislative process in nigeria a challenge
Accountability and transparency in legislative process in nigeria a challengeAccountability and transparency in legislative process in nigeria a challenge
Accountability and transparency in legislative process in nigeria a challenge
 
Governance crisis
Governance crisisGovernance crisis
Governance crisis
 
14-09-09-NR Advisory Note 1
14-09-09-NR Advisory Note 114-09-09-NR Advisory Note 1
14-09-09-NR Advisory Note 1
 
India legal 31 january 2016
India legal 31 january 2016 India legal 31 january 2016
India legal 31 january 2016
 
Handbook on security sector governance.5
Handbook on security sector governance.5Handbook on security sector governance.5
Handbook on security sector governance.5
 
Executive legislative relation in ghana
Executive legislative  relation in ghanaExecutive legislative  relation in ghana
Executive legislative relation in ghana
 
National security doctrine
National security doctrineNational security doctrine
National security doctrine
 
Bad Governance
Bad Governance Bad Governance
Bad Governance
 
Democratic oversight of the security sector the nigerian experience
Democratic oversight of the security sector   the nigerian experienceDemocratic oversight of the security sector   the nigerian experience
Democratic oversight of the security sector the nigerian experience
 
Decentralization and corruption in afghanistan
Decentralization and corruption in afghanistanDecentralization and corruption in afghanistan
Decentralization and corruption in afghanistan
 
Handbook on security sector governance.3
Handbook on security sector governance.3Handbook on security sector governance.3
Handbook on security sector governance.3
 
Good governance: A matter of choice or compulsion for the developing nations
Good governance: A matter of choice or compulsion for the developing nationsGood governance: A matter of choice or compulsion for the developing nations
Good governance: A matter of choice or compulsion for the developing nations
 
Federalsim and restructuring in nigeria
Federalsim and restructuring in nigeriaFederalsim and restructuring in nigeria
Federalsim and restructuring in nigeria
 
Party politics and democratic governance in nigerian local
Party politics and democratic governance in nigerian localParty politics and democratic governance in nigerian local
Party politics and democratic governance in nigerian local
 
Good governance module, Bishkek Academy, 2018
Good governance module, Bishkek Academy, 2018Good governance module, Bishkek Academy, 2018
Good governance module, Bishkek Academy, 2018
 
OVERSIGHT FUNCTIONS OF NIGERIA'S NATIONAL ASSEMBLY; 2011 - 2015
OVERSIGHT FUNCTIONS OF NIGERIA'S NATIONAL ASSEMBLY; 2011 - 2015 OVERSIGHT FUNCTIONS OF NIGERIA'S NATIONAL ASSEMBLY; 2011 - 2015
OVERSIGHT FUNCTIONS OF NIGERIA'S NATIONAL ASSEMBLY; 2011 - 2015
 
Raymond Atuguba on why we must eat the Ghana Constitution
Raymond Atuguba on why we must eat the Ghana ConstitutionRaymond Atuguba on why we must eat the Ghana Constitution
Raymond Atuguba on why we must eat the Ghana Constitution
 

Similar to IDLG discussion paper on Policy Paradigms, SNG, and The State Soveriegnty Gap in Afghanistan 21Jan2015 FINAL

The Role of Public Policy Research Institutions in Policymaking in Tunisia
The Role of Public Policy Research Institutions in Policymaking in TunisiaThe Role of Public Policy Research Institutions in Policymaking in Tunisia
The Role of Public Policy Research Institutions in Policymaking in Tunisia
Jasmine Foundation
 
Comparative Government of India and Afghanistan
Comparative Government of India and AfghanistanComparative Government of India and Afghanistan
Comparative Government of India and Afghanistan
HakeemJanMuffaker1
 
Yoyo
YoyoYoyo
Corporate Governance in Local Governments of the Public Sector for Sustainabl...
Corporate Governance in Local Governments of the Public Sector for Sustainabl...Corporate Governance in Local Governments of the Public Sector for Sustainabl...
Corporate Governance in Local Governments of the Public Sector for Sustainabl...
ijtsrd
 
Good Governance and Its Pillars
Good Governance and Its PillarsGood Governance and Its Pillars
Good Governance and Its Pillars
ijtsrd
 
A Study On Federalism
A Study On FederalismA Study On Federalism
A Study On Federalism
Sandra Valenzuela
 
An Overview Of The Transformation Agenda: The Ekiti State, Nigeria Experience
An Overview Of The Transformation Agenda: The Ekiti State, Nigeria ExperienceAn Overview Of The Transformation Agenda: The Ekiti State, Nigeria Experience
An Overview Of The Transformation Agenda: The Ekiti State, Nigeria Experience
Government of Ekiti State, Nigeria
 
Tata Kelola Pemerintahan yang Baik (Good Governance)
Tata Kelola Pemerintahan yang Baik (Good Governance)Tata Kelola Pemerintahan yang Baik (Good Governance)
Tata Kelola Pemerintahan yang Baik (Good Governance)
Tri Widodo W. UTOMO
 
2theconceptofgovernance 160625230938
2theconceptofgovernance 1606252309382theconceptofgovernance 160625230938
2theconceptofgovernance 160625230938
emmanuel edgar
 
The Concept of Governance
The Concept of GovernanceThe Concept of Governance
The Concept of Governance
Jo Balucanag - Bitonio
 
Good governance theory and practice08
Good governance theory and practice08Good governance theory and practice08
Good governance theory and practice08
Herry Prananto
 
Governance and politics in nigeria
Governance and politics in nigeriaGovernance and politics in nigeria
Governance and politics in nigeria
Olalere Taofeek Abiodun
 
Law, governance and the challenges for development
Law, governance and the challenges for developmentLaw, governance and the challenges for development
Law, governance and the challenges for development
Alexander Decker
 
UNPBSO Capstone - ELSA Final Report_FOR PUBLICATION
UNPBSO Capstone - ELSA Final Report_FOR PUBLICATIONUNPBSO Capstone - ELSA Final Report_FOR PUBLICATION
UNPBSO Capstone - ELSA Final Report_FOR PUBLICATION
Jue Gao
 
20090502 porj-s-07-00024[1]
20090502 porj-s-07-00024[1]20090502 porj-s-07-00024[1]
20090502 porj-s-07-00024[1]
Lichia Saner-Yiu
 
Role of Non Government Organisations and the Rti Act 2005
Role of Non Government Organisations and the Rti Act 2005Role of Non Government Organisations and the Rti Act 2005
Role of Non Government Organisations and the Rti Act 2005
HAQ: Centre for Child Rights
 
Public Administration as Governance
Public Administration as GovernancePublic Administration as Governance
Public Administration as Governance
Jo Balucanag - Bitonio
 
Governance issues by Mr-usman-asghar nust
Governance issues by Mr-usman-asghar nustGovernance issues by Mr-usman-asghar nust
Governance issues by Mr-usman-asghar nust
Nagarianz
 
Good Governance Leads To Flourish Society & Nation (BS SAP)
Good Governance Leads To Flourish Society & Nation (BS SAP)Good Governance Leads To Flourish Society & Nation (BS SAP)
Good Governance Leads To Flourish Society & Nation (BS SAP)
Neil Mathew
 
Response with 250 words each. Response 1Intergovernmenta.docx
Response with 250 words each.  Response 1Intergovernmenta.docxResponse with 250 words each.  Response 1Intergovernmenta.docx
Response with 250 words each. Response 1Intergovernmenta.docx
zmark3
 

Similar to IDLG discussion paper on Policy Paradigms, SNG, and The State Soveriegnty Gap in Afghanistan 21Jan2015 FINAL (20)

The Role of Public Policy Research Institutions in Policymaking in Tunisia
The Role of Public Policy Research Institutions in Policymaking in TunisiaThe Role of Public Policy Research Institutions in Policymaking in Tunisia
The Role of Public Policy Research Institutions in Policymaking in Tunisia
 
Comparative Government of India and Afghanistan
Comparative Government of India and AfghanistanComparative Government of India and Afghanistan
Comparative Government of India and Afghanistan
 
Yoyo
YoyoYoyo
Yoyo
 
Corporate Governance in Local Governments of the Public Sector for Sustainabl...
Corporate Governance in Local Governments of the Public Sector for Sustainabl...Corporate Governance in Local Governments of the Public Sector for Sustainabl...
Corporate Governance in Local Governments of the Public Sector for Sustainabl...
 
Good Governance and Its Pillars
Good Governance and Its PillarsGood Governance and Its Pillars
Good Governance and Its Pillars
 
A Study On Federalism
A Study On FederalismA Study On Federalism
A Study On Federalism
 
An Overview Of The Transformation Agenda: The Ekiti State, Nigeria Experience
An Overview Of The Transformation Agenda: The Ekiti State, Nigeria ExperienceAn Overview Of The Transformation Agenda: The Ekiti State, Nigeria Experience
An Overview Of The Transformation Agenda: The Ekiti State, Nigeria Experience
 
Tata Kelola Pemerintahan yang Baik (Good Governance)
Tata Kelola Pemerintahan yang Baik (Good Governance)Tata Kelola Pemerintahan yang Baik (Good Governance)
Tata Kelola Pemerintahan yang Baik (Good Governance)
 
2theconceptofgovernance 160625230938
2theconceptofgovernance 1606252309382theconceptofgovernance 160625230938
2theconceptofgovernance 160625230938
 
The Concept of Governance
The Concept of GovernanceThe Concept of Governance
The Concept of Governance
 
Good governance theory and practice08
Good governance theory and practice08Good governance theory and practice08
Good governance theory and practice08
 
Governance and politics in nigeria
Governance and politics in nigeriaGovernance and politics in nigeria
Governance and politics in nigeria
 
Law, governance and the challenges for development
Law, governance and the challenges for developmentLaw, governance and the challenges for development
Law, governance and the challenges for development
 
UNPBSO Capstone - ELSA Final Report_FOR PUBLICATION
UNPBSO Capstone - ELSA Final Report_FOR PUBLICATIONUNPBSO Capstone - ELSA Final Report_FOR PUBLICATION
UNPBSO Capstone - ELSA Final Report_FOR PUBLICATION
 
20090502 porj-s-07-00024[1]
20090502 porj-s-07-00024[1]20090502 porj-s-07-00024[1]
20090502 porj-s-07-00024[1]
 
Role of Non Government Organisations and the Rti Act 2005
Role of Non Government Organisations and the Rti Act 2005Role of Non Government Organisations and the Rti Act 2005
Role of Non Government Organisations and the Rti Act 2005
 
Public Administration as Governance
Public Administration as GovernancePublic Administration as Governance
Public Administration as Governance
 
Governance issues by Mr-usman-asghar nust
Governance issues by Mr-usman-asghar nustGovernance issues by Mr-usman-asghar nust
Governance issues by Mr-usman-asghar nust
 
Good Governance Leads To Flourish Society & Nation (BS SAP)
Good Governance Leads To Flourish Society & Nation (BS SAP)Good Governance Leads To Flourish Society & Nation (BS SAP)
Good Governance Leads To Flourish Society & Nation (BS SAP)
 
Response with 250 words each. Response 1Intergovernmenta.docx
Response with 250 words each.  Response 1Intergovernmenta.docxResponse with 250 words each.  Response 1Intergovernmenta.docx
Response with 250 words each. Response 1Intergovernmenta.docx
 

IDLG discussion paper on Policy Paradigms, SNG, and The State Soveriegnty Gap in Afghanistan 21Jan2015 FINAL

  • 1. Islamic Republic of Afghanistan Independent Directorate of Local Governance Policy Paradigms, Subnational Governance, and the State Sovereignty Gap in Afghanistan by Farid Mamundzay, Peter Blunt, Nader Yama, and Hamidullah Afghan IDLG Discussion Paper January 2015
  • 2. 2 Mamundzay, Blunt, Yama & Afghan January, 2015 Summary: It is argued that the battle to restore the sovereignty of the Afghan state will be won or lost subnationally. Victory will be more likely if, following Ghani and Lockhart (2008), citizen security can be assured; if the rule of law can be established and upheld without fear or favour; if reasonably effective, efficient, merit-based and accountable leadership and administrative means for service delivery can be institutionalised; and if social policies can be implemented that cut across regions and ethnic groups. However, progress towards these ambitious ends and the introduction in its support of pragmatic, evidence-based policy to strengthen the existing deconcentrated system of subnational governance (SNG) is hampered by stakeholder conceptual confusion about SNG, competing vested interests, and largely incommensurable and irreconcilable SNG policy paradigms. Success will depend on whether links can be forged between SNG pragmatic imperatives and political expediency. ‘The crisis of the state in developing countries and the unintended impact of global aid in weakening those states have undermined their sovereignty...If global security is dependent on the structural stability of functioning states, then the global system must, over the medium term, cohere around the goal of building sovereign states and make it a high priority’ (Ghani & Lockhart, 2008, p. 169). ‘The most important lines of policy (for the Afghan state) include... strengthening the foundational legitimacy of the government’ (Rubin, 2013, p. 440). 1 Introduction 1. The sovereignty and legitimacy2 of any state and the ability of its citizens to participate in and benefit from the development of national assets depend greatly on how the geographical pieces of the puzzle that comprise it are managed, jointly and severally. Subnational governance (SNG) should provide fundamental means for bridging what Ghani and Lockhart (2008, pp. 3-4) refer to as the ‘sovereignty gap’, or the gap between ‘the de jure sovereignty that the international system affords such states and their de facto...(inability) to provide even the most basic services for their citizens’ (parentheses added) 2. We shall argue that this maxim applies with particular force to fragile and war-torn states like Afghanistan, although difficult to implement because the obstacles to achieving good governance3 subnationally clearly are more pronounced in conditions of widespread and chronic conflict and where government institutions at the centre do not work as they should. In these respects Afghanistan is not an isolated case, being one of the ‘forty to sixty states, home to nearly two billion people,’ that, according to Ghani and Lockhart (2008, p.1), ‘are either sliding backward and teetering on the brink of implosion or have already collapsed.’ 1 The Carnegie Council describes Rubin as one of the world’s leading experts on Afghanistan, with ‘unmatched’ knowledge of the history of the region, ethnic rivalries and inter-relationships, and ‘insights into the failure of the state’. 2 Political legitimacy derives from the explicit and implicit recognition by the people of the rights of governments to govern, which in turn depends on government possessing sufficient authority to do so. Where governing authorities are not viewed as legitimate, social regulation is more difficult and costly. 3 We consider good governance to be merit-based, effective, equitable, efficient, transparent and accountable (see, for example, Blunt and Rondinelli, 1997).
  • 3. 3 Mamundzay, Blunt, Yama & Afghan January, 2015 3. Like Ghani and Lockhart (2008), we take the view that the standing-room-only sign in this development waiting room has been on for far too long - to everyone’s detriment - and that restitution is well overdue. 4. More so than most, in the case of Afghanistan, we shall show that if there is to be any chance of state sovereignty redemption the journey towards it must begin with SNG. Our argument is structured as follows. First, following Ghani and Lockhart (2008), we consider briefly the ten key functions of a sovereign state. Second, we discuss some of the major threats to state sovereignty that are evident in Afghanistan and demonstrate why it is that SNG has a vital role to play in their mitigation. Third, we outline the system of SNG in the country as it is now and discuss some of the necessary conditions for good policy development concerning it. Fourth, we analyse the competing paradigms4 of SNG policy that have evolved and some of the other state-building challenges that Afghanistan’s new government has to contend with. Fifth, on the basis of political economy and technical considerations and comparative research, we take a position on what broad form of SNG in the circumstances makes most sense for the country now and for the foreseeable future. In doing so, we adopt the widely received contingency approach to such matters (e.g., Blunt & Jones, 1992), where strategy and structure should depend on contextual factors, including those suggested by Ghani and Lockhart (2008). And finally, sixth, we consider whether the logic of our position concerning the preferred character of SNG will be able to withstand the conflicts of interest and other vicissitudes associated with the different competing policy paradigms that we identify. 5. The primary (qualitative) data marshalled in support of our arguments were gathered by the authors via participant observation from May 2014 to January 2015. During this period, all of the authors either held full-time positions in, or were associated with, the Independent Directorate for Local Governance (IDLG)5 of the Government of the Islamic Republic of Afghanistan – one as Deputy Minister (Policy), one as team leader of a development assistance project, and the others, respectively, as Director and Senior Adviser of the Strategic Coordination advisory unit within the organisation. The holding of these positions meant that the authors either instigated or supervised or were intimately involved in, or privy to, much of the SNG policy discussion and development that took place within IDLG and in government more generally (see, for example, Independent Directorate for Local Governance, 2014a, 2014b, and 2014c). The Notion of Sate Sovereignty 6. It is unusual for a country’s head of state to be someone who possesses scholarly and professional credentials that are directly related to state governance. This is currently the case in Afghanistan, where the newly-appointed president, Ashraf Ghani, has a rare combination of relevant experience – among others, as a professor and senior researcher of anthropology and political science in the USA, the Netherlands, and Afghanistan, as a minister of finance in Afghanistan and, for ten years, as chief anthropologist of the World Bank. He was named among the twenty most influential global thinkers of 2009 and 2010 for his work on fragile states (Rubin, 2013, p. xix). 4 A paradigm provides theoretical guidelines and sets the standards for legitimate work within the field it governs. It shapes and directs the ‘puzzle-solving’ activities of the groups of ‘normal scientists’ (Kuhn, 1970) that work within its confines (Blunt, 1997). Our use of the term ‘policy paradigm’ is analogous to the notion of ‘policy narrative’ (Sutton, 1999) that has become conventional wisdom in development circles. 5 IDLG is the lead central government institution responsible for non-sectoral sub-national government agencies in Afghanistan. Established by Presidential Decree in 2007, IDLG’s purpose is to ‘oversee’ or ‘monitor’ the performance of provincial, district and municipal offices. No other government agency has such responsibility.
  • 4. 4 Mamundzay, Blunt, Yama & Afghan January, 2015 7. His most important and most widely cited publication is his book, ‘Fixing Failed States’ (Ghani & Lockhart, 2008), whose well-constructed arguments deserve to be heard and to exert a significant influence on policy development under the new government. However, whether they will be able to withstand unscathed the violent swings and roundabouts of Afghan politics, and other pressures discussed below, is open to question. 8. The central contention of the book is that the gap between the de jure and de facto sovereignty of fragile states can only be bridged satisfactorily when governments are able to perform effectively, and largely unaided, ten core functions. Achieving these ends requires that the state and those who are providing it with different forms of assistance agree about what needs to be done, how, why, when and by whom. Importantly, it also requires that the incentives for the implementing agents of development assistance are structured to promote the weaning of the state from dependence on external support, which Ghani and Lockhart (2008) argue is not the case in Afghanistan. 9. The first core function of the sovereign state is to establish the rule of law, ‘the glue that binds all aspects of the state, the economy and society’ and provides citizens with a clear and transparent set of rules designed to govern their behaviour and that of other entities within its boundaries. Without exception, an effective legal system should hold government and others to account for their actions – whoever they are or whomever they may know - thereby building public trust and confidence in relevant institutions. In its absence, informal loci of power and control flourish, resulting in systemic malaise, particularly patronage and other forms of corruption. 10. The second core function, which is closely related to the first, concerns the state’s ability to monopolise the legitimate use of violence or force, against both external and internal threats and those who break the law. 11. The third function - ‘administrative control’ - among other things entails a merit- based government apparatus and leadership that is accountable within its own structures (upward accountability) and, crucially, to the citizens that it is meant to serve (downward accountability). Importantly for our discussion, and reinforcing the contingency approach that we advocate, such a system observes the principle that ‘when a lower level of government can handle a particular function, higher levels can stand back to monitor, plan and set the agenda’ (Ghani & Lockhart, 2008, p. 165). This implies that the delegation of authority to lower levels within government should be conditional, or contingent upon a range of relevant technical and non-technical (or political economy) variables. 12. Other core functions of the sovereign state include the sound management of public finance; investment in education (particularly professional and higher education) and training and public health; social policies that ‘cut across gender, ethnicity, race, class, spatial location and religion’; the provision of adequate physical infrastructure to all parts of the country; the formation of a market economy that is subject to checks and balances and where the roles of the state and the market are determined according to pragmatic as opposed to ideological considerations; the sustainable management of state assets in the best interests of all citizens, particularly natural resources and the protection of the commons (referring in both respects to the exemplar, Norway); and ‘effective public borrowing’ (Ghani & Lockhart, 2008). 13. As we shall demonstrate below, in fragile states like Afghanistan, good SNG and state sovereignty go hand-in-hand, in particular, with security, the rule of law, administrative control, and social policy development and implementation that cuts across geographical and ethnic boundaries. We argue that the condition of Afghanistan in these and other important respects should set limits on the character of SNG and the speed of its reform.
  • 5. 5 Mamundzay, Blunt, Yama & Afghan January, 2015 Challenges to State Sovereignty in Afghanistan 14. The task of establishing a well-functioning sovereign state has always been difficult and expensive in Afghanistan, partly because its geographical position for millennia has made it subject to geo-politically inspired attention from world powers, which has resulted in a series of protracted wars; partly because of the incompatible interests, and interference, of neighbouring states; and partly because of its large size, inhospitable terrain, and complex ethnic mix. Afghanistan has been, and remains, difficult to govern for the same reasons that it has been difficult to conquer. So much so that according to Rubin (2002), until the turn of the century, ‘the national government (was) irrelevant to most people’ and ‘didn’t touch most of the population’. Matters have improved since then, but not throughout the country, and not enough to impart significant legitimacy to government at the centre (Rubin, 2013, World Bank, 2014). 15. The roots of conflict in Afghanistan and its length and intensity make people of all ethnic groups fearful about the possible disintegration of the country. The decades of war have been fuelled partly as noted above by the interests of neighbouring states, with whom regional Afghan commanders have developed close ties, and partly by the geo-political interests of world powers. One notable effect of this is that the central government in Kabul has less influence over parts of Afghanistan than do Iran, Pakistan or Uzbekistan. Local commanders of private militias and insurgent groups who are sponsored by or allied with these regional powers remain a potent force in the country to this day and are among the biggest threats to state sovereignty and integrity (Rubin, 2013). 16. Such threats and incursions are piled on top of the infringements of state sovereignty in Afghanistan brought about by repeated foreign invasions and by the country’s long and heavy dependence on world powers for military, financial, and development assistance, a dependence that is as pronounced now as it has ever been. Other ingredients of state sovereignty, such as investments in people and infrastructure and international relations are compromised by such dependence. 17. These make ideal storylines for the Taliban and other subversive groups to weave into a picture of a lackey Afghan state that is incapable of exercising control over its own territory or providing security and basic services to its people, that is, a state that is sovereign in name only. The Year 2014 – the Pressure Mounts 18. The pressures on the Afghan state’s ability to demonstrate otherwise rose sharply in 2014. In a country that for generations has had to contend with far more than its fair share of cataclysms and sovereignty-threatening events, it may seem disingenuous to suggest that the year 2014 was an unusual one in terms both of the number and significance of the political and security challenges encountered by the state. But there are good grounds for making such a proposition. 19. First, in relation to security, it is estimated that the number of serious insurgency- related incidents in the country was approximately four times higher in 2014 than it had been in 2013 - with concomitant increases in civilian casualties (Graham-Harrison, 2014; United Nations Assistance Mission in Afghanistan, 2014). For an already war-weary citizenry, these developments cemented security’s place at the top of its list of concerns about the future (The Asia Foundation, 2014). 20. Unsurprisingly, there is considerable pent-up popular resentment about the suffering caused by the war, a condition made worse by the fact by the fact that, according to Amnesty International (2014), there is no institutionalised, credible means in government for
  • 6. 6 Mamundzay, Blunt, Yama & Afghan January, 2015 investigating and reporting publicly on civilian deaths and injuries caused by friendly military operations. And perpetrators are rarely held to account or pay adequate or any compensation for their misdeeds. This conveys the impression that they have been granted impunity by government and its foreign allies, thereby undermining in the eyes of the public important principles of the rule of law. Bennett (2014) observes that ‘the lack of accountability for killings of civilians by US/NATO forces in Afghanistan sends a message that foreign troops have free rein to commit abuses in Afghanistan and that the lives of Afghan civilians have little or no value’. Published in August 2014, the Amnesty International report examined 10 cases that had caused the deaths of a total of 140 Afghan civilians. None of the cases had been properly investigated either by foreign or Afghan authorities. 21. The gravity of such incidents for state sovereignty is illustrated by Rubin’s (2013, p. 427) account of the wrongful killing by US troops at a checkpoint of an Afghan boy on a bicycle. The troops who had shot the boy kept the body for three days (a grave offence in Islam), while the family waited outside the military camp for its return. ‘After the body was finally returned, the village elders met and decided to join the Taliban to fight the Americans.’ 22. Second, and equally significant, was the prospect of a new government and the protracted and acrimonious contest between the two main candidates for president, which was underlain by interplay between a wide and complex range of patronage, ethnic and regional vested interests. 23. The delay in the formation of a new government had been caused by allegations of fraud surrounding the presidential election and tensions between the rivals that had risen accordingly, to the point of deadlock. Recognising the serious implications of an impasse, the American Secretary of State, John Kerry, flew to Kabul in July and again in early August 2014 in an attempt to broker an agreement on the basis of an impartial re-assessment of the validity of all of the votes that had been cast. This helped to break the deadlock and a government of national unity providing positions at its apex for both candidates – president and a new position of chief executive - was formally announced in the second half of September and the new president was inaugurated on 29 September 2014.6 Cabinet positions were formally announced in mid-January 2015. This constituted the country’s first major political transition as a nascent democracy. 24. Third was the acceleration of the phased withdrawal of foreign troops and, by the end of 2014, the assumption by government of complete responsibility for the maintenance of national security and law and order. 25. Fourth, and simultaneously, management of the state became severely constrained by significant and sudden reductions in the national budget and in donor funding. These were seismic changes to an environment of government whose baseline was already extremely turbulent and unpredictable. 26. The stresses imposed on the state by the military, political and budgetary transitions were compounded because they were contemporaneous and because transition scheduling was nearly always driven by internal and external political agendas rather than development need. 6 As much as anything, breaking the deadlock was important because it prevented the Taliban from being able to ‘claim to have proven that the system of government adopted by Afghans with international support after their ouster from power cannot function. The increasing capacity of the (Afghan) security forces and the extent of their international backing (would) be irrelevant if they (had) no legitimate (government) authority to defend’ (parentheses added) (Rubin, 2014).
  • 7. 7 Mamundzay, Blunt, Yama & Afghan January, 2015 27. An optimistic interpretation of the political transition would be to say that it constituted an unprecedented symbol of progress and of shared interest among the main power blocs in striving for peace and stability. A less sanguine view would be that the fundamental points of difference and open antagonism between the parties are unlikely to dissipate and that they will plague all major decisions, particularly those concerning who will get what key positions (e.g., provincial governor) and other spoils in government. The national mood could be said to reflect this in that only a slight majority of 55% of the population think that the country is moving in the right direction (The Asia Foundation, 2014). The Year 2015 – a Development Watershed 28. The year 2015 is likely to be a particularly telling one in so far as the battle to restore state sovereignty in Afghanistan is concerned, one that is dependent upon whether sufficient security can be maintained for government to establish the rule of law, deliver services and sustain development, and whether political differences can be set aside – or assuaged sufficiently - in the interests of state sovereignty and the common good. 29. The main impediment to attaining state sovereignty is the Taliban, who will either have to be defeated militarily or accommodated and appeased politically. The less likely the former, the more government will be compelled to consider a political settlement with a resurgent Taliban, emboldened by the withdrawal of foreign troops and bent on exploiting the deep political divides in a new and vulnerable government. It seems unlikely that peace and stability will be attained and sustained without a rapprochement, a move that would likely receive strong support from Pakistan, a long-term backer of the predominantly Pashtun Taliban (Harding, 2001). Tomsen (2014), for example, observes that ‘the new Afghan government…will face long odds in its effort to hold off the Taliban and counter Pakistani meddling.’ 30. The escalation of serious security incidents in the country in 2014 as compared to 2013 and the perpetuation of hostilities and attacks throughout the country during what in the past has always been the winter off-season mean that the pressure is on government like never before. Bearing out the plausibility of a rapprochement scenario, by January 2015, the international news media were reporting that talks with the Taliban had begun, but that offers of positions in the new government had been rejected by them (Loyn, 2015), suggesting that they will not be bought-off easily. 31. Fundamental differences concerning the constitution and the bases of the legitimacy of the state and the position of women in society are some of the main stumbling blocks in negotiations (e.g., Kane, 2015). Even so, some suggest that despite these obstacles and its reliance on ‘on strongmen, manipulation, and patronage networks’, the Taliban may be shifting its ground politically, towards Afghan mainstream politics. For its part, mainstream politics is said to be ‘becoming more violent and ruthless and in a sense...moving closer to the Taliban’s way of doing things’ (Giustozzi & Mangal, 2015), perhaps indicating that both sides are keen to do business and that the Taliban recognise the importance of establishing political legitimacy. 32. These events and prospects bring to an already traumatised nation heightened uncertainty, conflict and stress and they raise considerably the likelihood and stakes of government failure. 33. One effect of these conditions should be to increase the importance that government attaches to those few levers of state sovereignty influence over which it has some measure of direct control. As noted above, these include what Ghani et al. (2006) and Ghani and Lockhart
  • 8. 8 Mamundzay, Blunt, Yama & Afghan January, 2015 (2008) refer to as ‘administrative control’, ‘delineation of state and citizen rights and duties’, ‘monopoly of the means of violence’, and the establishment of the rule of law. Ghani et al. (2006, p. 7) describe the interplay between some of these factors in terms of: ‘...both the breadth and depth of the reach of a state’s authority over its territory...In order to establish and maintain administrative control, a state requires the following: the existence of a coherent set of rules that determine the division of responsibilities horizontally and vertically across functions of the state and between hierarchical levels; the recruitment of civil servants; the spatial and functional division of administrative roles; and flows of resources. The extent to which the citizens of a state accept that the promulgation and enforcement of these rules serves the interest of the majority is crucial to engendering trust between the state and its citizens and giving citizens a sense of belonging. The structure of administration could vary in practice between highly centralized to highly federated depending on the historical and cultural context’. The Importance of SNG to State Sovereignty 34. In the general sense just described, but particularly in the other respects mentioned above and below, the form and quality of SNG is clearly vital to state sovereignty and legitimacy in Afghanistan. 35. The new government’s recognition of the importance of this link is evident in the ‘Realising Self-Reliance’ document it presented to the London Conference in December, 2014, where it made clear its intention to review (2010) sub-national policy in order ‘to provide greater clarity on the roles and responsibilities of sub-national officials’ and to create governance circumstances that enable ‘people across all provinces (to) have greater voice.’ (Government of the Islamic Republic of Afghanistan, 2014, p.12). These policy intentions target questions of upward and downward accountability, which are of critical significance to the establishment of state sovereignty, a maxim emphasised throughout Ghani and Lockhart (2008) and by others like Bene and Neiland (2006) and IDLG (2014c). 36. The wait-and-see nature of the national mood on questions of governance provides government with an opportunity to demonstrate its credentials in these and other important respects, but as we have shown popular patience is – and has been - under severe strain, limiting the time available for government to be seen to be doing the right things. Strengthening those drivers of state sovereignty that are integral to SNG will be central to this, as confirmed by the latest survey results, which show that at the local level, apart from security, the main problems reported by citizens have to do with electricity, roads, drinking water, education, and healthcare (The Asia Foundation, 2014). Necessary Conditions: Conceptual Clarity and Altruism 37. To begin to address these issues coherently and constructively, ideally all stakeholders should be clear about the main features of the different forms of SNG that are available, or what the options are (e.g., World Bank Institute, 1999; IDLG, 2014c), and their intentions should be genuinely altruistic and aligned. However, as elsewhere, policy discourse surrounding SNG in Afghanistan does not enjoy these advantages, albeit that among some of the parties involved, there is recognition of the need for conceptual clarity, which has resulted in steps being taken towards establishing this necessary condition (e.g., Adam Smith International, 2014, 2015). 38. Such clarity should begin with agreement concerning the nature of the existing system of subnational governance in Afghanistan, which can be characterised as being deconcentrated but with limited elements of political, fiscal, and market decentralisation.
  • 9. 9 Mamundzay, Blunt, Yama & Afghan January, 2015 Services are delivered subnationally by geographically dispersed units or offices of line ministries and are controlled from the centre - although, as in any organisational structure, varying degrees of delegation of authority and responsibility are possible within the system. Political decentralisation manifests itself in the form of elected provincial councils, which are the main means of downward accountability. But the roles and functions and authorities of the councils, and of councillors, are ill-defined in existing legislation. The same is true of the crucial positions of provincial and district governor, whose formal authorities are limited and poorly defined (reducing upward accountability), but who wield enormous informal power and thereby pose a significant challenge to the legitimacy of government at the centre. 39. Below, we shall refer to the existing system of SNG in Afghanistan as being ‘deconcentrated’, but this remains a term that is perhaps not as widely understood to comprise what we have just suggested as it might be. 40. The second condition – comprising altruism and alignment, in the sense described by Ghani and Lockhart (2008) – is more problematic, because of the variety of interests represented among both internal and external actors. Despite rhetorical claims to the contrary, these interests are incommensurable and therefore largely irreconcilable and levels of altruism are variable (e.g., Chang, 2002, 2009). 41. We would expect state sovereignty not to fare very well under these circumstances – according to some, state compliance being a much more sought after quality in the development partners of rich countries (e.g., Chang, 2002, 2009; Chomsky, 2010; Roy, 2004). Ghani and Lockhart (2008) reach somewhat similar conclusions: ‘The central task that the aid system should perform—namely, generating prosperity by bringing a global knowledge of stocks and flows to countries without it—is not being performed. In view of the fact that it comprises extractive industries and technical assistance brigades, the aid system—instead of opening countries up to legitimate entrepreneurial activity—epitomizes the side of capitalism that is fundamentally exploitative’ (p. 86). 42. For these reasons and others that we shall examine below, achieving policy discourse coherence on SNG in Afghanistan, as elsewhere, is likely to be less than straightforward. The Democracy Promotion Paradigm 43. When it comes to the distribution of power subnationally, among local actors, Tomsen’s (2014) observations on the subject of SNG suggest that the two main Afghan schools of thought are not that far apart. The more radical of the two is said to be prepared to countenance devolution of limited authority to ‘elected provincial and district governors’, while the ‘others believe that the status quo, with power rigidly centralised in Kabul, will remain necessary as long as the insurgency continues’. 44. Tomsen’s account and his use of words like ‘rigidly’ imply that he subscribes to the ideologically-inspired conventional wisdom of much of the donor community, a view that sees extreme forms of decentralisation as being the end point of a virtuous natural progression that begins with central control. In contrast, we take the view that this policy paradigm confuses means and ends. It does so by assuming that a particular means of SNG (decentralisation) is a desirable end in itself, based largely on ideological convictions associated with ‘democracy promotion’. It ignores the substantial body of research evidence that shows what limited success - in terms of development ends like poverty and inequality reduction - decentralisation has enjoyed in developing countries, but particularly in fragile states (Blunt & Turner, 2005, 2007). Rubin (2013, p. 122) agrees: ‘The international
  • 10. 10 Mamundzay, Blunt, Yama & Afghan January, 2015 community involved in assisting Afghanistan in such matters pays lip service to the agenda of strengthening the central government but works pragmatically with a variety of regional forces, reinforcing fragmentation. Global trends that see decentralisation as conducive to democracy and grassroots development legitimate such decisions.’ 45. As, for example, in Cambodia, we suggest below that at least some national politicians are likely to see things very differently, perhaps regarding democracy promotion per se as having little value, except as rhetorical window dressing (Blunt & Turner, 2005). Political Expediency Paradigms 46. The vision statements or election manifestos of the new president and the chief executive suggest that they disagree on matters that affect SNG, although it is still not yet clear where the two main power blocs in government stand on this issue. Disagreement between them seems likely for the reasons that we have already given, but the question is by how much and with what implications for SNG? Rubin (2014), for example, observes that they have different views about ‘the degree of centralisation of the state; the balance of power between regional, ethnic, and tribal coalitions; control over the security forces; the role of the former armed resistance, and how all of these will affect the distribution of the diminishing flows of foreign aid’. 47. Taken at face value, these are clearly important areas of potential difference. But even in the best of circumstances we know that political election platforms and promises are unreliable guides to policy enactment by elected governments. Politicians everywhere are notorious for saying one thing during elections and doing something quite different once they are in office. The correlation between political rhetoric and policy reality is noted more for its weakness than strength (Blunt, 2009, p. 94). 48. In relation to ‘the degree of centralisation of the state’, we argue below that there are good reasons for supposing that, despite what may have been said by each side, in some fundamental respects it is unlikely that there will be marked divergences between them on this matter, and that this makes good sense. 49. We say this because it seems probable that, when it comes to making decisions about SNG, the nature of informal power relations between the centre and the periphery, and among different entities at the periphery, which have been problematic in Afghanistan historically (Rubin, 2002, 2013), are likely to be of paramount concern to both parties. To the extent that some measure of control cannot be exercised over sub-national powerbrokers,7 the state will be significantly weakened and could fail altogether. That is to say, the multiplicity of sites of informal power outside of Kabul (warlords and some governors) that continue to contest control over territory and other key resources among themselves and with the centre, and openly to flout its authority, threaten to fragment the state and to make it ungovernable (though local power brokers seem not, as in some other countries, to be interested in secession). This conclusion is supported by Turner (2006, p. 1), who states that, in Afghanistan, ‘Intra-state instability is the dominant pattern which needs to be overcome.’ 50. In support of our conjecture, both sides are said by Rubin (2013, p. 440) to recognise that devolution or ‘the decentralisation of service provision’ is not just a technical matter, and that it could inflame ‘the most potentially divisive issue, namely the relation of the state to different ethnic groups and in particular to Pashtuns and non-Pashtuns’. 7 How this is done will need to take account of the dynamics of such local power relations, rather than to rely solely or largely on capacity building or attempt to overwhelm them by force (Lister, 2007; Mukhopadhyay, 2009).
  • 11. 11 Mamundzay, Blunt, Yama & Afghan January, 2015 51. This makes it unlikely that either side in the new government will want to move quickly – or, for the time being, perhaps at all - towards ceding greater formal power to the periphery, that is, to move away from the current system of deconcentration towards a more devolved system of SNG. This is not to say, however, that the two sides would necessarily agree about how the current system of deconcentrated SNG should be strengthened and developed – for example, differences of opinion are likely to emerge when it comes to the distribution of authority and resources within it and in relation to procedures governing the appointment and removal of governors (the potential for disagreement concerning the latter is illustrated in IDLG, 2014a). Contingency-based Paradigm 52. If we are to take seriously the view expressed by Ghani and Lockhart (2008, p. 199) - that ‘tailoring to context’ should be ‘a key attribute of national programs’ – then we submit that the circumstances of the country discussed so far and other considerations set out below make this an optimal strategy for the new government to pursue. 53. Somewhat paradoxically, perhaps, in the short to medium terms this will mean that in order to make government more relevant to the scattered and diverse population that occupies Afghanistan’s vast geographical space, it will be necessary first to establish effective and legitimate government at the centre (Rubin, 2007, 2013). 54. The main reconstruction task in Afghanistan should therefore be the accommodation and control of regionally-based (informal) powers by a central power that has the capacity to deliver basic services of reasonable quality throughout the country and to perform the other tasks of a sovereign state that we have outlined, a goal that for the most part is still far from being achieved. This view is endorsed by Blunt and Turner (2007, p. 120) in their assessment of research evidence from a number of conflict and post conflict states: ‘Deconcentration is particularly relevant for weak or fragile states as it can be seen as a method of increasing the strength of the state to provide its citizens with the services they are entitled to....a strong foundation of prior centralization is a necessary basis for successful political decentralisation. Deconcentration can be seen as a step in this direction.’ 55. Support for this conclusion can also be found in Rubin’s research, which over many years has shown that among ordinary Afghans ‘there is a universally expressed preference for being governed by a central authority that obeys some laws and where a district governor can be changed by the central government if he or she didn’t do the right thing’ (Rubin, 2002). As they did then, most people now want to get rid of the ‘rule of the gun’ and regard a strong central government as being the principal means of achieving this. In 2002, Rubin observed that Afghans wanted this because they ‘associate local control with control by gunmen and warlords’, a situation that in many parts of the country is likely to have become a lot worse. Ten years later, in 2013, his views on the subject are largely unchanged, although qualified by the observation that continuing popular support for centralisation would depend very much on how it was implemented, noting that increasingly many Afghans want to be ‘participating citizens’ as opposed to ‘passive subjects’ (Rubin, 2013, pp. 130-131). Challenges and Consequences of Failure 56. The challenges of strengthening government at the centre are likely to be much the same now as they were in 2007 when Rubin observed that important central institutions are ‘deeply corrupt and plagued by a lack of basic skills, equipment and resources. Without effective and honest administrators, police, and judges, the state can do little to provide internal security – and if the government does not provide security, people will not recognise
  • 12. 12 Mamundzay, Blunt, Yama & Afghan January, 2015 it as a government’. Everyone knows that there is much still to do in all of these respects, and that the deep funding cuts that are in prospect will make everything more difficult. These challenges are more pronounced at the periphery. 57. Yet, while more difficult, the importance of making real and rapid progress in these respects is greater now than ever before. And the consequences of failing in this endeavour are not difficult to imagine, among them a descent ‘into a full-scale civil war’ (Tomsen, 2014) or ‘a slide into chaos when the Americans leave and the Afghan army is pushed into a “fortress Kabul” strategy, as the Taliban re-take the countryside, worsening ethnic conflict, and neighbouring states arm their Afghan proxies, and a refugee crisis ensues as millions of Afghans again flee the country’ (Rashid, 2013). It is clearly not in the interests of western powers, of either of the two main figures in government or of the Kabul political elite in general for any of these things to happen. As Rubin (2014) points out, all of the parties want to win, ‘but they know that they could all lose.’ Pragmatic Imperatives of SNG ‘Once Afghanistan no longer fears for its own disintegration, it will become more feasible for the state to experiment with forms of local governance and decentralisation...in order to provide the services that the Afghan people are now demanding’ (Rubin, 2013, p. 441). 58. Against this background, when it comes to the distribution of power and resources in government subnationally, the rationality of keeping things more or less as they are (for now and the foreseeable future) and trying to make them work better has a firm basis in national and sub-national political economy, in the unpalatability to western powers and to both sides in government and the Kabul political and business establishment of a return to chaos and, most importantly, in popular preferences. 59. This position, which relies on the contingency-based paradigm, is reinforced by a number of other considerations. First, it is well-established in the research literature that where government institutions at the centre are weak and patronage is systemic devolving power and resources to local governments simply provides sustenance for the spread of patronage to the periphery and its entrenchment (e.g., Blunt et al., 2012a, 2012b). In his discussion of governance in Afghanistan, Rubin (2002) expresses the same view when he says that ‘international experience with devolution/decentralisation is that if you try it in a rather chaotic situation without a strong legal system, it is a formula for corruption rather than effective self-government’. The classic statement of this position is Diamond (1999): ‘Where hierarchical chains of particularistic, patron–client relationships are already the dominant mode of politics, shifting discretionary financial authority from the central to the local level may simply shift the locus of clientelism and corruption from the central to the local arena, making these problems even tougher to control’ (p. 244). 60. Second, as elsewhere, significant change towards decentralised government in Afghanistan would require additional human and financial resources, and would lead inevitably to bureaucratic inflation, at a time when government revenues and donor funding are in steep decline and government capacity sub-nationally is weak and is likely to remain so for some time to come - as Rubin (2013, p. 440) confirms: ‘the (Afghan) state is simply too weak to manage decentralised service provision.’ Again, this is a conclusion that is well supported by comparative research: ‘is it wise in circumstances where central governance institutions are widely recognised as being weak...to embark on a difficult and costly devolution programme? Would scarce development resources be better spent initially on strengthening these core institutions – the legal and judicial systems for example – or on
  • 13. 13 Mamundzay, Blunt, Yama & Afghan January, 2015 supporting existing systems of deconcentration that are the only existing means of (weak) service delivery in crucial sectors such as health, education, and agriculture?’(Blunt & Turner, 2007, p. 122). 61. Third, in any case, the evidence shows that more often than not devolved systems of SNG fail to deliver in practice what they promise in theory, and that the chances of success are sharply reduced where governance institutions at the centre are weak. In support of this conclusion, recent research on these issues sponsored by the World Bank concludes that decentralisation or ‘participation... appears to affect the distribution of benefits in ways that suggest that capture is often not “benevolent” or altruistic’ (Mansuri & Rao, 2013, p. 6). 62. A similar conclusion is reached by Blunt and Turner (2007, p. 127): ‘Experience has shown how even the best-intentioned experiment in democratic devolution can fail to live up to expectations and in some instances can leave people, especially the poor and disadvantaged, worse off than before. Yet, despite weak central institutions of governance and high cost, development practice nearly always eschews deconcentration in favour of democratic decentralisation although this latter label is frequently in name only.’ 63. And, most tellingly, fourth, there is considerable evidence from conflict and post- conflict states to suggest that more devolved systems of SNG can lead to the intensification of inter-regional and inter-ethnic conflict (Schou & Haug, 2005). 64. Accordingly, we submit that the short to medium term task in Afghanistan should be to construct a state structure that is strong enough at the centre to unite the country, provide security, and establish the rule of law and, within the existing system of deconcentration, allows enough authority to permeate to lower levels in the provinces to give citizens – who, according to Rubin (2013), ‘are politicised as never before’ – the opportunity to exercise some influence on policies and practices that affect their lives. Conclusion ‘A weak state results when internal and external actors prove themselves incapable of aligning around the goal of sovereignty’ (Ghani & Lockhart, 2008, p. 177). 65. Our discussion of the necessary conditions for coherent SNG policy discourse in Afghanistan and of the three main SNG policy paradigms suggests that aligning external and internal actors around the goal of state sovereignty – and, hence, bridging the sovereignty gap - will be far from straight forward. Of the two necessary conditions, achieving conceptual clarity is feasible, but reconciling competing vested interests and ensuring undiluted or uniform altruism seem to us to be much less so. This suggests that it may not be just a question of incapability among stakeholders that inhibits alignment around the goal of state sovereignty, but also – and more importantly - their willingness to do so. 66. These shaky foundations underlie SNG policy paradigms that for the most part in any case are incommensurable and irreconcilable. The democracy promotion paradigm of SNG is ideologically-driven and therefore - as a matter of faith – unlikely to be amenable to rational argument. Its principal interest is to promote ‘democracy’ and decentralisation come what may, that is, irrespective of what the evidence might suggest will be the benefits for ordinary people or for state sovereignty. Paradigm failures, which in any event may not be measured in the above terms, can always be rationalised or written-off as a function of some combination of recalcitrant and corrupt local officials, a lack of political will, and insufficient
  • 14. 14 Mamundzay, Blunt, Yama & Afghan January, 2015 capacity, that is, as the fault of the victim. These conditions are unlikely to be peculiar to Afghanistan (e.g., Blunt, 2014). 67. The political expediency paradigms, on the other hand, are supremely pragmatic but only in so far as certain categories of evidence are concerned. It is here we believe that the best prospects lie for acceptance of the pragmatic imperatives that we advocate as a basis for strengthening and maintaining for the foreseeable future the current system of deconcentrated SNG in Afghanistan. 68. Making it clear that over-ambitious and premature devolution is likely to increase significantly political risk and constrain progress towards state sovereignty is the key to producing SNG policy that is optimal for equitable and sustainable development. If decentralising government and ceding greater formal authority to governors, some of whom already openly flout the authority of the state, will undermine the rule of law; if it will intensify inter-ethnic and inter-regional conflict that is already at a high pitch; if it will make security in those parts of the country controlled or threatened by the Taliban and other insurgent groups more difficult to attain; if, because service provision is unlikely to be improved, it will undermine the legitimacy of government at the centre; if it will increase the financial burden on government without providing any certainty of increased fiscal return or improved service delivery; if it will direct scarce investment away from ‘human capital’ and physical infrastructure; and if it will limit the ability of government to introduce social policies that benefit all regions and ethnic groups more or less equally. Then, for all of these reasons and because, as we noted earlier, all political interests want to win but they also realise that they could all lose, politics and pragmatism could coalesce around maintaining and strengthening the existing deconcentrated system of SNG. 69. But despite the evident weight of political and pragmatic argument in its favour, this happy conclusion is far from being a policy slam dunk. As with policy development everywhere, resistance, serendipity, opportunism, and irrationality will all come in to play (Sutton, 1999), and could tilt the balance against an optimal development or state sovereignty outcome. It remains to be seen whether government can resist these pressures and achieve policy discourse leadership or dominance in the interests of state sovereignty and the common good. 70. All stakeholders have vital roles to play in this. Clearly, the more that development assistance and different arms of government can align themselves with the president’s vision of state sovereignty the better. We have shown here the strong links that exist between SNG and important aspects of state sovereignty, providing clear direction for all of those who want to see Afghanistan standing on its own feet as soon as possible, direction that should help to make development assistance more cost-effective because it will be more likely to succeed. And if, as Ghani and Lockhart (2008) suggest in our opening quote, genuinely sovereign states are the building blocks of a secure, stable and peaceful global order then striving for and supporting state sovereignty in Afghanistan could have much wider implications. 71. It should be stressed, however, that the vision of alignment expressed by the president and outlined here is not simply donor coordination by another name. As we have shown, the president’s vision of state sovereignty is explicit about the necessity for national leadership and it is equally explicit about what in broad terms will need to be done. 72. Each stakeholder is likely to face different constraints in conforming to these imperatives. However, the job of reconciling such constraints with the national interest will be made easier if donors and other stakeholders can adopt the contingency-based approach to programme design and policy development advocated by the president and in this paper.
  • 15. 15 Mamundzay, Blunt, Yama & Afghan January, 2015 73. IDLG, for example, has adopted this approach in relation to forming a view about the preferred character of SNG, and herein has demonstrated the links between policy in favour of strengthening the existing system of deconcentration and state sovereignty. It is incumbent upon other government and non-government stakeholders to do the same with respect to their own areas of responsibility. References Adam Smith International (2014). Briefing Note on SNG Terminology. Kabul, December, mimeo, pp. 5. Adam Smith International (2015). Policy Discussion Paper: Subnational Governance and State Sovereignty. Kabul: January, mimeo, pp. 12 Amnesty International (2014). Left in the Dark: Failures of Accountability for Civilian Casualties Caused by International Military Operations in Afghanistan. August, London: Peter Benson House. Retrieved on 24 September, 2014 from: http://www.amnesty.org/en/library/asset/asa11/006/2014/en/c628b1a4-821f-4168-a583- ac4a6159986e/asa110062014en.pdf Bene, C. & Neiland, A.E. (2006). From Participation to Governance. Institute for the Sustainable Development of Fisheries: Portsmouth, UK. Bennett, R. (2014). Afghanistan: Urgent Enquiry Needed after New US Airstrike Increases Civilian Death Toll. Afghanistan Times, 14 September, p. 6. Blunt, P. (1997). Prisoners of the Paradigm: Process Consultants and ‘Clinical’ Development Practitioners. Public Administration and Development, 17: 341-349. Blunt, P. (2009). The Political Economy of Accountability in Timor Leste: Implications for Public Policy. Public Administration and Development, 29: 89-100. Blunt, P. (2014). Whose Resources are they anyway? Community Development Agreements in the Mongolian Mining Sector. Progress in Development Studies, 14(4): 383-399. Blunt, P., and Jones, M. (1992). Managing Organisations in Africa. Berlin & New York: Walter de Gruyter, pp. 356 & xiv. Blunt, P., and Rondinelli, D. (1997). Reconceptualising Governance. New York: Management Development and Governance Division, UNDP, Discussion Paper Number 2. Blunt, P., and Turner, M. (2005). Decentralisation, Democracy and Development in a Post- Conflict State: Commune Councils in Cambodia. Public Administration and Development, 25 (1): 75-87. Blunt, P., and Turner, M. (2007). Decentralisation, Deconcentration and Poverty Reduction in the Asia Pacific. In S. Cheema & D. Rondinelli (Eds.), Decentralized Governance: Emerging Concepts and Practices. Cambridge, Mass.: Brookings Institution Press and the Ash Institute for Democratic Governance and Innovation, John F.K. Kennedy School of Government, Harvard University, pp. 115-130. Blunt, P., Turner, M., and Lindroth, H. (2012a). Patronage, Service Delivery and Social Justice in Indonesia. International Journal of Public Administration, 35(3): 214-220. Blunt, P., Turner, M., and Lindroth, H. (2012b). Patronage’s Progress in Post-Soeharto Indonesia. Public Administration and Development, 32(1): 64-81. Chang, Ha-Joon. (2002). Kicking Away the Ladder: Development Strategy in Historical Perspective. London: Anthem Press. Chang, Ha-Joon. (2009). Bad Samaritans. New York: Bloomsbury Press. Chomsky, N. (2010). Hopes and prospects. London: Penguin. Diamond, L. (1999). Developing Democracy: Towards Consolidation. Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press.
  • 16. 16 Mamundzay, Blunt, Yama & Afghan January, 2015 Ghani, A., Lockhart, C., and Carnahan, M. (2006). Closing the Sovereignty Gap: an Approach to State-Building. London: Overseas Development Institute, Working Paper 253. Retrieved on 16 December, 2014 from: http://www.odi.org/sites/odi.org.uk/files/odi-assets/publications-opinion- files/2482.pdf Giustozzi, A., & Mangal, S. (2015). Violence, the Taliban and Afghanistan’s 2014 Elections. United States Institute of Peace, 7 January. Retrieved on 16 January, 2015 from: http://www.usip.org/publications/violence-the-taliban-and-afghanistan-s-2014- elections Ghani, A., & Lockhart, C. (2008). Fixing Failed States: A Framework for Rebuilding a Fractured World. Oxford: Oxford University Press. Government of the Islamic Republic of Afghanistan (2014). Realising Self-Reliance: Commitments to Reforms and Renewed Partnership. December, Kabul & London, London Conference on Afghanistan, mimeo, pp. 24. Graham-Harrison, E. (2014). Afghanistan's war takes heavy civilian toll, says United Nations report. The Guardian, 9 July. Retrieved on 3 October, 2014 from: http://www.theguardian.com/world/2014/jul/09/afghanistan-war-civilian-toll-united- nations-report Harding, L. (2001). Taliban Moderates Offered Future Role: Powell Backs Call to Afghan Pragmatists. The Guardian, 17 October. Retrieved on 16 January, 2015 from: http://www.theguardian.com/world/2001/oct/17/pakistan.afghanistan IDLG (2014a). Procedures for the Recruitment, Selection, Appointment, and Removal of Provincial Governors. September, Kabul: IDLG Policy Brief, pp. 7. IDLG (2014b). IDLG Strategy, Structure, and Functions: Adjusting to Conditions of Environmental Hostility and Complexity. Kabul: IDLG Discussion Paper, pp. 17. IDLG (2014c). Enhancing IDLG’s Contributions to national and Sub-National Governance: Rationale, Strategic Opportunities, and Reform Proposals. October, Kabul: IDLG Strategic Review – Discussion Paper, pp.49. Kane, S. (2015). Talking with the Taliban: Should the Constitution be a Point of Negotiation? Unites States Institute of Peace, 12 January. Retrieved on 16 January, 2015 from: http://www.usip.org/publications/talking-the-taliban-should-the-afghan-constitution- be-point-of-negotiation Kuhn, T. S. (1970). ‘Logic of discovery or psychology of research?’ in Lakatos I., and Musgrave A. (eds.), Criticism and the Growth of Knowledge. London: Cambridge University Press. Lister, S. (2007). Understanding State-Building and Local Government in Afghanistan. London: London School of Economics, Crisis States Research Centre, Working Paper no. 14. Retrieved on 28 August, 2014 from: http://www.lse.ac.uk/internationalDevelopment/research/crisisStates/download/wp/w pSeries2/wp142.pdf Loyn, D. (2015). Taliban ‘Reject Offer of Afghan Government Posts’. BBC News Asia. Retrieved on 14 January, 2015 from: http://www.bbc.com/news/world-asia-30737664 Mansuri, G. & Rao V. (2013). Localising Development: Does Participation Work? Washington DC: World Bank. Mukhopadhyay, D. (2009). Warlords as Bureaucrats: the Afghan Experience. Washington DC: Carnegie Endowment for International Peace, Carnegie Papers, Middle East Programme, Number 101. Retrieved on 27 August, 2014 from: http://carnegieendowment.org/files/warlords_as_bureaucrats.pdf
  • 17. 17 Mamundzay, Blunt, Yama & Afghan January, 2015 Rashid, Ahmed. (2013). Afghanistan after the War: Is Peace Possible. New Republic, 28 March. Retrieved on 8 August, 2014 from: http://www.newrepublic.com/article/112680/afghanistan-after-war Roy, A. (2004). An Ordinary Person’s Guide to Empire. Cambridge, Mass.: Southend Press. Rubin, B. (2002). The Fragmentation of Afghanistan: State Formation and Collapse in the International System. Talk delivered to the Carnegie Council, 25 June, 2002. Retrieved on 3 August, 2014 from: http://www.carnegiecouncil.org/studio/multimedia/20020625/index.html Rubin, B. (2007). Saving Afghanistan. Foreign Affairs, January/February. Retrieved on 16 August, 2014 from: http://www.foreignaffairs.com/articles/62270/barnett-r- rubin/saving-afghanistan Rubin, B. (2013). Afghanistan from the Cold War through the War on Terror. Oxford: Oxford University Press. Rubin, B. (2014). The Election is the Enemy. Foreign Policy, 2 April. Retrieved on 13 August, 2014 from: http://www.foreignpolicy.com/articles/2014/04/02/afghanistan_elections_taliban_gha ni_attacks Schou, A., & Haug, M. (2005). Decentralisation in Conflict and Post-Conflict Situations. Oslo: Norwegian Institute for Urban and Regional Research, Working Paper 139. Retrieved on 31 October, 2014 from: http://www.nibr.no/filer/2005-139.pdf Sutton, R. (1999). The Policy Process: An Overview. London: Overseas Development Institute, mimeo, pp. 35. The Asia Foundation (2014). Afghanistan in 2014: a Survey of the Afghan People. Kabul: The Asia Foundation, pp. 251. Retrieved on 9 December, 2014 from: http://www.asiafoundation.org/publications/pdf/1425 Tomsen, P. (2014). The Good War? What went wrong in Afghanistan and How to make it Right. Foreign Affairs, 93(6). Transparency International (2014). Corruption Perception Index 2013. Retrieved on 7 August, 2014 from: http://www.transparency.org/cpi2013/results Turner, M. (2006). State Consolidation and Subnational Governance in Afghanistan, Paper presented at International Research Symposium on Public Management 10 (IRSPMX), Glasgow Caledonian University, 10-12 April. United Nations Assistance Mission in Afghanistan (2014). 2014 Sees Highest Civilian Casualty Figures Recorded. New York, 19 December. Retrieved on 20 December, 2014 from: http://unama.unmissions.org/Default.aspx?tabid=12254&ctl=Details&mid=15756&It emID=38492&language=en-US World Bank (2014). Critical Administrative Constraints to Service Delivery: Improving Public Services in Afghanistan’s Transformational Decade. Kabul: World Bank, pp. 133. World Bank Institute. (1999). Decentralisation Briefing Notes. Retrieved on 18 August, 2014 from: http://siteresources.worldbank.org/WBI/Resources/wbi37142.pdf