SlideShare a Scribd company logo
Unconventional monetary policies help to finance the public sector’s
debt burden. While a number of these policies were crucial and
beneficial to managing the financial crisis, they also come with significant
costs. The unintended consequences include potential asset price
bubbles, an impaired credit intermediation channel and increasing
economic inequality.
Financial repression:
The unintended consequences
Today’s low interest rate environment
is not only driven by macroeconomic
factors, but also by policy actions
that help governments deal with the
high sovereign debt burden.
These policies – called “financial
repression” – have unintended
consequences for both households
and long-term investors like
insurance companies or pension
funds.
Foreword
Central banks have done an extraordinarily good job of stabilising
financial markets, restoring economic confidence and fighting the
threat of deflation – no question about that. But seven years after
the financial crisis, interest rates are still being kept at historically low
levels, mainly due to the ongoing low growth environment.
Do low interest rates really help to overcome the global economic
malaise? Doubts abound. They certainly do have one effect:
That is, helping governments to direct funds to themselves to finance
their debt and lower their funding costs – a set of policies known
as financial repression.
Indeed, policymakers’ actions to manage the financial crisis
resulted in significant benefits for society at large. But today, the
advantages of those ongoing actions are outweighed by their
costs. As well as resulting in lower interest earnings on savings,
financial repression serves as a disincentive for policymakers to
tackle pressing public policy challenges and thus advance the
structural reform agenda. Furthermore, continued intervention by
policymakers calls into question the existence and independence
of markets more generally. Central bank financial market engineering
is no substitute for economic reforms.
Swiss Re has developed its own index to track financial repression.
This publication contributes to quantifying its costs. We want to weigh
in on today’s key public policy debate, adding valuable insight into
the unintended consequences of financial repression and preserving
the important opportunities for long-term investors.
Guido Fürer
Group Chief Investment Officer
Swiss Re
2  Swiss Re Financial repression: The unintended consequences
Table of contents
 
Introduction 4
Overview of global monetary policy 6
Unintended consequences of financial repression 10
Asset price bubbles 10
Impact on private households 13
Impact on institutional investors 17
Inflation and credibility 19
Exiting monetary policy 22
Capital market outlook 22
Sovereign vulnerability 23
Infrastructure investments and growth 26
Concluding remarks 29
Appendix 32
4  Swiss Re Financial repression: The unintended consequences
Introduction
The costs of financial
repression are significant.
Since the financial crisis,
US savers alone have lost
roughly USD 470 billion in
interest rate income, net of
lower debt costs. The policy
is not only supported by
central banks’ actions, but
also by regulatory rules that
favour sovereign bonds.
Today’s low interest rate environment is
not only driven by macroeconomic
factors, but foremost by policy actions
that help governments deal with the
high sovereign debt burden. Regulatory
rules that support financial repression
by favouring sovereign bonds have also
been put in place.
The impact of financial repression on
markets, so far, is undisputable:
Continued increases in bond prices,
expensive stocks and relatively low
volatility – a situation which is hardly
sustainable.
Moreover, the policy actions that cause
financial repression entail a number of
unintended consequences (see page 10).
These include potential asset price
bubbles, convergence in asset allocation
strategies of otherwise heterogeneous
financial market participants and an
increase in economic inequality. With
regards to the latter, the impact of
foregone interest income for households
and long-term investors is substantial.
At the same time, the equity rally has
predominantly benefited society’s
wealthiest. Furthermore, central bank
independence and credibility is
increasingly questioned. The longer such
extraordinary and unconventional
monetary policies are in place following
the move from crisis management to
crisis resolution, the more challenging
the “exit phase” will be (see page 22).
The costs of financial repression are
significant. Let’s take the US as an
example. Had the Federal Reserve (Fed)
followed a policy based on the Taylor
rule1, the interest rate target would have
been roughly 1.7 percentage points
higher on average than it was in the
period 2008–2013. When also taking
into account longer-term rates (and their
extent of being below their “fair
equilibrium value”) and the lower debt-
related expenditures for households,
the net tax on US savers amounts to
USD 470 billion of foregone interest
rates over that period. Simultaneously,
wealthier savers benefited from the
equity rally, bringing along new issues
related to economic inequality. Box 1
shows the cumulative effect in the US
since the financial crisis.
1 Taylor-rule rate = Neutral real policy rate + core CPI + 0.5*(Inflation target – core CPI) + 0.5*
(NAIRU – unemployment rate)
Swiss Re Financial repression: The unintended consequences  5
Without a doubt, the legacy of the crisis – highly leveraged economies – is still
present today. But resolving this legacy issue with continued application of past
interventionist instruments does not incentivise the much needed structural reforms
and private capital market activities. Financial repression has induced a re-allocation
of capital across markets and greatly enhanced the role of public markets at the
detriment of private market activities. Artificially low – or in some cases even
negative – interest rates break the credit intermediation channel which can crowd
out viable private investors. This lowers their ability to channel funds to the real
economy. Today’s broken intermediation channel needs to be repaired durably. For
that, more private capital market solutions are required. Investments in infrastructure
(see page 26) serve as growth-enhancing strategies that could repair some
of this damage, especially if financed by the private sector and traded in private
capital markets.
The following sections provide an overview of global monetary policy and analyse
the unintended consequences of financial repression. Additionally, central bank
policy “exit” is reviewed in the context of the capital market outlook and sovereign
vulnerability. Finally, infrastructure investments are outlined as a means of
addressing the broken credit intermediation channel and weak economic growth.
USD 8tn USD 3tn
USD 500bn USD 1tn
USD 400bn USD 2tn
USD 9tn
Foregone US households’ interest
income net of lower debt costs
Box1: Cumulative since the global financial crisis
6  Swiss Re Financial repression: The unintended consequences
Overview of global monetary policy
In the aftermath of the 2008–2009 global financial crisis, central banks around
the world undertook extraordinary monetary policy measures to help stabilise
financial markets, restore economic growth and fight the threat of deflation. These
unconventional policy measures included liquidity provisions, the purchase of
financial assets (quantitative easing, QE) and forward guidance (see Box 2, which
quantifies Swiss Re’s financial repression index). Among other effects, this led to
a massive increase in central banks’ balance sheets; both in absolute terms and as
a percentage of GDP (see Figure 1).
Source: Swiss Re, Bloomberg
More than half a decade after the end of the recession, central bank policy rates in
the US, UK, Eurozone and Japan remain at historic lows, and unconventional policy
measures are still in place (Figure 2).
Federal Reserve QE ended in October 2014; Fed remains “patient in beginning
to normalise the stance of monetary policy”
European Central
Bank
After cutting its key interest rates to the “zero-bound”, the ECB
announced that it will implement a broad-based asset purchase
programme with a size of EUR 60 billion per month
Bank of England Completed three rounds of QE, total of GBP 375 billion in assets;
set out ‘phase 2’ of forward guidance in February 2014 aimed at
eliminating the spare capacity in the economy
Bank of Japan Quantitative and qualitative easing policy, targeting an increase
in the monetary base of JPY 80 trillion per year “as long as it is
necessary” for achieving a 2% inflation rate
But central bank policies have started to take diverging paths. While the Fed and
the Bank of England (BoE) are preparing to start increasing interest rates at some
point in 2015, the European Central Bank (ECB) and Bank of Japan (BoJ) maintain
a commitment to extraordinary measures. This divergence is likely to become even
more apparent in the future. Interest rate hiking cycles have historically been
less coordinated than easing cycles; economic fundamentals and the reactions
of individual central banks are what matter now.
Figure 1:
Balance sheets of G4 central banks,
from 2000 onwards (USD trillion)
0
2
4
6
8
10
12
BoE BoJ Fed ECB
2012201020082006200420022000
Figure 2:
Unconventional policies of G4
central banks
Swiss Re Financial repression: The unintended consequences  7
US Eurozone UK Japan EMs
Normalising
monetary
policy.
Going back
to interest
rate policy
From
fragmenta­
tion to robust
integration.
A complex
undertaking
Policy
normalisation
to start
gradually.
UK economy
outperforms
the Eurozone
From
deflation to
reflation.
The jury
is still out
Addressing
spillovers from
G4 central
bank policies.
See market
reaction in May
2013 as the Fed
tapered
Source: Swiss Re
Figure 3:
Transition from liquidity-driven to
growth-driven markets
0
1
2
3
4
5
6
7
Index level
Financial repression index
January 2000	 January 2002	 January 2004	 January 2006	 January 2008	 January 2010	 January 2012	 January 2014
	  Monetary      Regulatory      Others
Box 2: Swiss Re financial repression index
Financial repression reflects the ability
of policymakers to direct funds to
themselves that would otherwise go
elsewhere.
Swiss Re has developed its own
financial repression index that is
based on the following three broad
components (see Appendix for
methodology):
a. Monetary: i) real yields, ii) difference
of long-term government bond
yields to their ‘fair value’, iii) central
bank QE purchases and holdings,
and iv) divergence of policy rate
from Taylor rule
b. Regulatory: i) regulatory risk and
(ii) the consequences thereof,
namely a) asset encumbrance and
b) availability of high-quality assets
c. Others: Banks’ domestic sovereign
debt holdings and capital flow
development
The index suggests that financial
repression is currently high on a
historical basis, though down from its
2011–2012 peak. The major driver
of change post-2007–2008 has been
monetary policy (grey). Regulatory
changes featured prominently post-
2011 (blue). Within the blue area,
the contribution from the inflexibility
of banks’ balance sheets (asset
encumbrance) has declined from the
peak in 2011–2012. Debt holdings
and capital flows (light blue, i.e.
“others”) have been a stronger driver
more recently.
Source: Swiss Re
8  Swiss Re Financial repression: The unintended consequences
Financial repression has broken
the credit intermediation channel.
Long-term investors are crowded
out of some markets, lowering
their ability to channel funds to
the real economy. Infrastructure
investments would repair
this damage and address weak
economic growth.
Swiss Re Financial repression: The unintended consequences  9
10  Swiss Re Financial repression: The unintended consequences
Unintended consequences of financial repression
Why do central banks engage in unorthodox monetary policies? Key objectives
include bringing inflation back to target, stabilising financial markets and fostering
economic growth. While the jury is still out on their success and ability to achieve
those goals, one effect is clear: Low interest rates help governments to fund their
debt. In other words, they are able to channel funds to themselves – referred to
as financial repression.
This type of policymaking comes at a cost. So far, central bankers have argued that
the benefits of quantitative easing and other unorthodox measures outweigh the
costs. However, exiting ultra-easy monetary policy will become harder with time and
the unintended consequences will become more apparent. These include potential
asset bubbles, a financial repression “tax”, increasing economic inequality, the
potential of higher inflation and reputation damage for central banks.
The debate among central bankers on the potential unintended consequences of the
“Great Monetary Experiment” has already intensified somewhat, in particular related
to the implications for economic inequality2. However, the focus on the topic remains
rather tepid at best and more informed public policy discussions are necessary.
Asset price bubbles
Financial markets hit lows in 2009, but have since strongly recovered. The SP500
has advanced by roughly 200% since March 2009 when it hit its lowest point.
At least part of this rally was liquidity-driven as a result of extraordinary central bank
policy measures (see Figure 4).
Source: Swiss Re, Bloomberg
The low yield environment post-2008 has seen investors shift from investment grade
into higher yielding assets and emerging market bonds, particularly over the period
2009–2012 (Figure 5).
Figure 4:
Fed balance sheet and SP500
400
600
800
1000
1200
1400
1600
1800
2000
2200
2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014
SP 500 index level Fed balance sheet (USD trn) -rhs (right-hand side)
0.5
1.0
1.5
2.0
2.5
3.0
3.5
4.0
4.5
5.0
2 E.g. see ECB Governing Council member Mersch, 17 October 2014, “Monetary policy and economic
inequality“; Fed Chairwoman Yellen, 17 October 2014, “Perspectives on inequality and opportunity from
the survey of consumer finances“
Swiss Re Financial repression: The unintended consequences  11
Source: Swiss Re, EPFR Database
There has been some convergence between the US and Europe in fixed income
asset allocation since 2000, notably in the insurance sector (see Figure 6). European
insurers’ fixed income allocation rose from around 40% in 2000 to almost 55%
currently. At the same time, equity allocation has dropped significantly. It is currently
at 25–30% as opposed to 32–38% in 20004. Pension funds increased their equity
allocation in Europe and the US, with the majority of the increase being in the US.
Source: Swiss Re, OECD Database. Note: Europe represents the average of the UK, Germany,
France, Italy and Spain
The significant price appreciation across asset classes post-2009 suggests the risk
of a market-wide asset price bubble. Forward equity price to earnings (P/E) ratios
have moved above their long-term average, while cyclically-adjusted Shiller P/E
Figure 5:
Strong fund inflows into DM and EM bond
funds3 over 2009–2012 (% of assets under
management)
-10
0
10
20
30
40
50
60
EM Bond Funds
Corporate HY Bond Funds
International Bond Funds
201420132012201120102009
%
Figure 6:
Insurers’ and pension funds’ allocation
to fixed income assets over time
20
30
40
50
60
70
US insurers
European insurers
European pension funds
US pension funds
20132012201120102009200820072006200520042003200220012000
3 Equity fund flows have been less predictable over the years, but there were net inflows into EM and
Japanese equity funds. Cumulatively since 2009, inflows into EM and Japanese equity funds totaled
40% and 30% of AuM respectively, vs. roughly zero into US and Western European equity funds
4 The equity allocation figures might also include other equity-linked investments apart from listed or
private stocks, ie variable-yield securities and units in unit trusts. This is based on OECD data covering
the broad insurance industry across countries
12  Swiss Re Financial repression: The unintended consequences
Unintended consequences of financial repression
ratios are back at pre-crisis levels. The same is true for investment grade corporate
credit and securitised product spreads. Some asset class segments look particularly
overvalued. These include collateralised loan obligations (CLOs), high-yield corporate
credit and leveraged loans. Housing markets are vulnerable to easy money and asset
bubbles. Markets in London, China and in some Scandinavian countries are most
at risk of a significant correction. The longer the current monetary policy stance is
maintained, the longer those risks will continue to build up.
Clearly, financial market excess (FME) has been building up due to increased risk
appetite and low market volatility. The Swiss Re FME index is now close to pre-crisis
average levels (see Figure 7). The Fed has warned about these risks on a number
of occasions, even though they have largely been engineered by the Fed itself. In a
February 2013 speech, former Fed Governor Jeremy Stein highlighted the over­
heating in credit markets. In her semi-annual testimony, Fed Chairwoman Janet Yellen
later identified small cap, biotech and social media stocks as being highly valued
relative to the historical norm.
Source: Swiss Re, Bloomberg, Morningstar, DB, MS
Note: The index is based on a variety of measures that cover different aspects of potential market
exuberance: (i) market risk sentiment: Swiss Re Market Risk Appetite Index; (ii) market activity: MA deal
count; (iii) leverage: CCC issuance share of HY issuance and net debt/EBITDA for high-yield; (iv) fund flows:
equity and high-yield mutual fund flows; (v) valuation: cyclically adjusted P/E ratio (SPX) and high-yield
spreads to US Treasuries; and (vi) volatility: realised stock market volatility (SPX). The index is calculated as
the average of the Z-scores for the nine factors, based on the five-year pre-crisis period from 2002 to 2007,
and is then transformed to a 0–1 scale. The index frequency is weekly.
Figure 7:
US Financial Market Excess (FME) index
0.0
0.2
0.4
0.6
0.8
1.0
1.2
2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 20132012 2014
Swiss Re Financial repression: The unintended consequences  13
Impact on private households
The prevailing low interest rate environment and the strong performance of
financial assets due to loose monetary policy have a profound impact on savers and
institutional investors’ portfolio returns. Some regard this as another example of
financial repression. Reinhart and Sbrancia (2011) summarise it thus as: “unlike
income, consumption, or sales taxes, the ‘repression’ tax rate […] may be a more
politically palatable alternative to authorities.”
Unconventional central bank policies not only affect the interest-bearing assets of
households (accounting for roughly 30% of household wealth), but other investments
such as equity (~40% of household wealth, including mutual funds) and real estate
(25% of household wealth) – see Figure 8.
Source: Swiss Re, US Federal Reserve
Households are being ‘taxed’ as they do not earn interest on their deposits that they
otherwise would. In case of negative real interest rates, they even experience a
devaluation of their savings in real terms. Had the Fed followed a simple Taylor rule5,
the policy target rate would have been roughly 1.7 percentage points higher on
average in the period 2008–2013.
Assuming the lower rate had been passed on to depositors, the foregone annual
interest earnings from savings accounts amount to USD 14 000 per adult for the top
1% wealthiest; and USD 160 for the bottom 90%. For pension and life insurance
assets, with 10-year US bond yields having traded roughly 1.2 percentage points
below their ‘fair value’6 on average since 2008, foregone interest for the top 1%
amounts to roughly USD 9 000 per adult. Clearly, low interest rates also reduce debt
costs; with lower mortgage rates providing the bulk of the relief7. On a net basis,
the foregone interest earnings amount to roughly 0.3% of total financial assets for
both the top 1% and top 10% wealthiest adults (see Figure 9). For the remaining,
the significant advantage of lower debt costs (mainly mortgages) translates into
a ‘subsidy’ of 0.3% of financial assets. Since the financial crisis, the total cumulative
Figure 8:
US household wealth asset allocation
0%
10%
20%
30%
40%
50%
60%
70%
80%
90%
100%
Other
Fixed income
Equity
Currency and deposits
Mutual funds
Life insurance and pension
Real Estate
2013201220112010200920082007
USD trn
77 66 68 72 73 79 88
5 Taylor-rule rate = Neutral real policy rate + core CPI + 0.5*(Inflation target – core CPI) + 0.5*
(NAIRU – unemployment rate)
6 “Fair value“ computed as potential GDP growth rate + inflation target of 2%. Note: this analysis ignores
any realised gains or losses on the fixed income holdings, taking a pure running investment income view
7 As for pension and life insurance assets, the assumption is that debt costs have been 1.2% lower than
“fair value“, on average
14  Swiss Re Financial repression: The unintended consequences
net “tax” on all US households amounts to roughly USD 470 billion. This
represents an average “tax” of 0.2% per annum on total financial wealth (including
interest-bearing assets and equities), or 0.4% of total interest-bearing assets.
Source: Swiss Re, Credit Suisse Global Wealth Databook, 2013, Wolff, 2012, “The Asset Price Meltdown
and the Wealth of the Middle Class“
Meanwhile, the wealthier savers have benefited more from the equity rally with the
top 1% having 50% of their financial assets invested in equities (while the bottom
90% only allocates 9% on average). Assuming that, on average, US savers have
profited from a 100% appreciation of their equity portfolio during the 2009–2013
period (and ignoring the losses from pre-crisis legacy holdings), this results in a gain
of USD 3.7 million for the top 1% of households and USD 7 300 for the bottom 90%.
As a percentage of total financial wealth, the top 1% has thus recorded a 50% gain
while the bottom 90% only registered a 12% profit (see Figure 10). This suggests
that monetary policy and central bank asset purchases have aggravated economic
inequality via equity price inflation. Overall, the actual value of equity holdings in
US household portfolios has risen by roughly USD 9 trillion since 20088.
* Assuming US savers have profited from a 100% appreciation; ignoring legacy holdings.
Note: Figures rounded
Source: Swiss Re, Credit Suisse Global Wealth Databook, 2013, Wolff, 2012, “The Asset Price Meltdown
and the Wealth of the Middle Class“
Figure 9:
Annual impact on US savers’ interest
earnings/costs from (too) low interest rates
Three categories: The wealthiest 1%,
the wealthiest 10% and the remaining 90%,
from 2008–2013, per adult
–5
0
5
10
15
Debt costs
Pension and life insurance
Deposits
Bottom 90%Top 10%Top 1%
13.9
9.1
3.5
–1.9
–4.1
0.2 0.2
–0.6
3.0
USD, in thousand % of total financial wealth
–0.4
–0.3
–0.2
–0.1
0.0
0.1
0.2
0.3
0.4
Net “tax” as % of total financial wealth (rhs)
Figure 10:
Average gains from the 2009–2013 equity
rally in US household portfolios (per adult)*
0
500000
1000000
1500000
2000000
2500000
3000000
3500000
4000000
Gain per adult
bottom 90%top 10%top 1%
3.7mn
USD % of total financial wealth
690tsd
7tsd 0%
10%
20%
30%
40%
50%
60%
70%
80%
Gain as % of total financial wealth (rhs)
Unintended consequences of financial repression
8	US Federal Reserve data
Swiss Re Financial repression: The unintended consequences  15
Finally, low interest rates may also have impacted house prices through lower
mortgage costs, thus increasing refinancing activity and housing demand.
Historically, a decline in the real long-term interest rate by 100 basis points was
found to have increased house prices by up to 7%9. A simple regression of the log
house price (FHFA US house price index) on the real 10-year US interest rate10
confirms these findings (impact is found to be around 5%). This translates into an
increase in household wealth of roughly USD 1 trillion based on the assumption
that long-term real interest rates have been roughly 1.2 percentage points below
their ‘fair value’, on average, since 2008. As a percentage of total financial wealth,
the bottom 90% wealth class has profited most, even though from an absolute
perspective the gain for the top 10% richest is still multiple times higher.
In conclusion, the impact of financial repression on US household wealth has been
lower net interest income, which might be understood as a “tax” on savers. It has
been counterbalanced by the increase in wealth due to the appreciation in the value
of equity and real estate holdings (see Figure 11).
Estimated impact Wealth distribution effect
The financial repression
“tax”
USD –470 billion Top 10% are taxed, while bottom
90% are subsidised
Change in household
wealth
House price increase*:
USD +1 trillion
From an absolute perspective,
equity and house price gains
have mostly benefited the
richer part of society. As a %
of financial wealth, housing
gains have helped the poorer
part of society
Equity gains**:
USD +9 trillion
* Assuming +5% is attributable to central bank policy. The wealth impact from rising home values was
likely offset by homeowner deleveraging
** Reflecting the value change of US households equity positions in their portfolios. Arguably, this
assumption is rather optimistic as the pure stock price appreciation attributable to financial repression
was likely much smaller
Whether the increase in wealth has led to the so-called “wealth effect” (ie impact
on actual consumption) is questionable. Unlike interest income on deposits, equity
and real estate value appreciation are not realisable cash gains immediately available
for consumption. Also, property prices have not yet fully recovered their loss from
the 2008–2009 period. Households are thus still worse off compared to pre-crisis.
Moreover, outstanding mortgage debt has continued to decline even after the trough
in home prices11. This indicates that the gain in households’ real estate portfolio values
was at least partially offset by reducing the value of mortgage debt.
Overall, there is no clear evidence of equity-related gains having translated into
additional consumption and thus no real economic growth (see Figure 12, only a
very weak relationship). A similar picture holds for the “wealth effect” related to
housing. As a result, the increase in financial and housing wealth has – at best – only
marginally benefited the real economy. Indeed, households’ foregone interest
income (the “tax”) was certainly not positive for spending. Meanwhile, the equity
and property value gains had a significant impact on wealth inequality, as the richest
households have profited significantly in absolute terms. The “wealth effect” is also
questionable given population aging and the life-cycle hypothesis12. At lower interest
rates, more aggregate savings are required for an aging population to maintain their
consumption level post-retirement (see Box 3).
Figure 11:
Impact of financial repression – the “tax”
and household wealth
9	Glaeser  Gottlieb, 2010, “Can cheap credit explain the housing boom“
10	As suggested by Glaeser  Gottlieb, 2010
11	Since mid-2011, US loan-to-value ratios have dropped from almost 55% to 42% with outstanding
mortgage debt having declined by 5% (Source: Bloomberg)
12	An economic theory that relates to individuals‘ consumption habits over the course of a lifetime.
16  Swiss Re Financial repression: The unintended consequences
Source: Hoisington Quarterly Review and Outlook, Q1 2014
Figure 12:
Real consumption vs. SP500
(1930–2013)
Real per capita PCE, % change
Real SP 500, % change
R2
= 0.27
15
10
5
0
–5
–10
–15
–50 –40 –30 –20 –10 0 5040302010
Elderly-dependency ratios (%)
Box 3: Demographic trends, low interest rates and the “wealth effect”
Population aging is likely to become
a bigger focus for financial market
developments in the coming years,
especially as the dependency ratios in
many major economies are to rise
significantly. The available labour force
will decrease, and the elderly will
increasingly make up a larger propor­
tion of the population. This will bring
further social and economic challenges.
As seen in the Figure below, Japan,
Spain and Germany are at the higher
end of the spectrum with dependency
ratios of at least 60% expected by
2050. Meanwhile, the US population
is expected to age much slower.
With most governments already facing
unsustainable debt, rising age-related
spending only aggravates the problem.
Moreover, there is a risk that the finan­
cing need will further create incentives
for governments to implement even
more expansionary policies.
Putting this aside, several question
marks emerge related to current
financial repression policies: According
to the life-cycle hypothesis of con­
sumption and saving, during retire­ment
an aging population reduces its savings
and disinvests its asset holdings in
order to support consumption. This
means that the “wealth effect”, as
reflected by policies to support the
equity market for fuelling consumption
growth, will be even less effective.
At lower interest rates, more needs
to be saved on aggregate for an aging
population in order to maintain the
consumption level post-retirement
when the accumulated savings are
spent.
0
10
20
30
40
50
60
70
80
2050
2030
2015
2010
India
Brazil
China
US
Australia
Canada
Switzerland
Spain
UK
France
Italy
Germany
Japan
Unintended consequences of financial repression
Source: UN Database
Swiss Re Financial repression: The unintended consequences  17
Impact on institutional investors
Institutional investors such as re/insurers and pension funds hold a significant part
of their assets in fixed income securities given their business need to match long-
term liabilities. As such, their investment income has been significantly impacted by
prevailing low interest rates. Life insurers in particular struggle to meet their
guaranteed rates. Although the guaranteed life insurance credit rate has declined in
recent years, it is still significantly above the respective 10-year government bond
yield (around 2.5% vs ~1% typical European 10-year bond yield13).
Re/insurers’ running yields14 have declined over recent years, following a similar path
as 30 year US Treasury yields (see Figure 13). Had US Treasuries (or German Bunds)
been trading closer to their ‘fair value’ (implied by potential GDP growth and an inflation
target of 2%), running yields would have been roughly 0.5–1 percentage points
higher on average for the 2008–2013 period15. Given re/insurers’ allocation to fixed
income assets of 50–60%16, this would have translated into roughly USD 20–40
billion additional income overall for both US and European insurers. A sensitivity
analysis of insurers’ running investment income to additional running yield is shown
in Figure 14. For pension funds, the impact of 1 percentage point of additional
running yield would be similar – a total additional income of USD 40–50 billion per
annum. The pension industry’s asset base is somewhat larger, but the average
allocation to fixed income is smaller than in the insurance sector.
Source: Swiss Re, Bloomberg, OECD Database, Insurance Europe, 2014, “European Insurance in Figures“
Figure 13:
US insurers’ running yields vs. 30 year
Treasuries
2%
3%
4%
5%
6%
7%
30yr UST yield (%)
US PC running yield
US LH running yield
Q4/01 Q4/03 Q4/05 Q4/07 Q4/09 Q4/11 Q4/13
Figure 14:
Insurers‘ investment income as a function of
additional running yield
0
10
20
30
40
50
60
70
80
European insurers
US insurers
0.10.30.50.70.91.11.31.5
USD bn
Additional running yield
13	EIOPA Financial Stability Report, May 2014
14	Annualised investment return based on average invested assets. Excludes realised gains/losses
15	Computed as actual 30Y government bond yield – [“fair value“ (which is assumed to hold for
10Y government bonds) + historical 30Y–10Y term premium of ~50bps]
16	Insurance Europe, 2014, “European Insurance in Figures“ and OECD Database. Note that the fixed
income allocation might be understated due to OECD classification of “miscellaneous assets“, mutual
funds, unit trusts, money market fund shares etc.
18  Swiss Re Financial repression: The unintended consequences
Though this analysis ignores any realised gains or losses from the fixed income
assets, Box 4 shows the tremendous impact that financial repression can have
on long-term investors.
“Tax” on pension funds and insurers
Average of the US, UK and Eurozone
Box 4: The “opaque tax” on long-term investors
Foregone interest income represents
an “opaque tax” on insurance
companies and pension funds – on
average currently estimated at 0.4–
0.8% p.a. of their total financial assets
for the US and Europe (see Figure
below). Assuming a 4–8 times asset
leverage embedded in insurers’
balance sheets, this would translate
into a drag on RoE of ~4% on average.
Besides the impact on long-term
investors’ portfolio income, the
consequences for financial market
intermediation are not negligible either:
Crowding out investors due to
artificially low yields will also reduce
the diversification of funding sources to
the real economy, thus representing a
risk for financial stability and economic
growth at large.
-1.5
-1.0
-0.5
0.0
0.5
1.0
1.5
Penison funds’ tax
Insurers’ tax
Jan 1997 Jan 2001 Jan 2005 Jan 2009 Jan 2013
“Financial Repression” Zone
Note:
A positive number indicates
a “tax” on the investor,
while a negative number can
be considered a “subsidy”
% of Total Financial Assets
Unintended consequences of financial repression
Source: Swiss Re
Swiss Re Financial repression: The unintended consequences  19
Inflation and credibility
Major central banks face a trade-off between supporting economic recovery and
contributing to the further potential build-up of financial and economic imbalances,
in particular the risk of long-term inflation. While inflation is currently low, this could
change over the medium- to long-term given extraordinarily accommodative central
bank policies and the gradual reduction of economic overcapacity.
Longer-term inflation risks are to the upside given the current Fed focus on growth,
which has contributed to the massive increase in central bank balance sheets (see
Figure 15) and the high sovereign debt levels across major economies. The danger
of a hyper inflationary scenario, however, remains distant.
Source: Swiss Re, Bloomberg. Note: Central banks include BoE, BoJ, ECB, Fed and SNB. World GDP is
based on PPP in current USD trillion
Post-financial crisis, there is a broad consensus that central banks should increase
their monitoring of financial stability risks in the context of overall macro stability.
This switch in focus would raise the potential politicisation of central banks. An
increase in supervisory powers must be balanced with maintaining central bank
independence. Fed Chairwoman Janet Yellen has repeatedly stated that she does
“not presently see a need for monetary policy to deviate from a primary focus on
attaining price stability and maximum employment, in order to address financial
stability concerns.” Instead, she believes that “a macro prudential approach to
supervision and regulation needs to play the primary role.”17
Figure 15:
Sum of major central bank balance sheets,
in USD and as % of world GDP
0
2
4
6
8
10
12
2013201120092007200520032001
USD trn
0%
2%
4%
6%
8%
10%
12%
in USD trn
as a % of GDP (rhs)
17	Fed chairwoman Yellen‘s central banking lecture at the IMF, 2 July 2014
20  Swiss Re Financial repression: The unintended consequences
Central banks face a trade-
off between supporting
economic recovery and
contributing to the further
potential build-up of
financial and economic
imbalances.
Swiss Re Financial repression: The unintended consequences  21
22  Swiss Re Financial repression: The unintended consequences
While some economies are recovering, notably the UK and the US, growth is more
fragile in Japan and in the Eurozone. But even in countries experiencing better
growth, central banks have yet to gain sufficient confidence in the strength of their
economies to start exiting the extraordinary monetary conditions enacted post-
2008.
At some point central banks will have to exit unconventional monetary policies and
raise rates again. So, what will happen if they change their accommodative approach?
Most significant for the global economy will be the tightening of US monetary policy.
This will imply long- and short-term challenges. In the short-term, they will include:
(i) maintaining credible and consistent communication as economic data further
improves; (ii) preventing unnecessary and excessive market volatility amid the even­
tual shift to a more hawkish stance; and (iii) technical implementation of the exit,
with the new fixed-rate reverse repo facility likely to play an important role in the
Fed’s exit toolkit.
Long term, the fundamental question arises of whether too much is being asked of
central banks. As already stated by Paul Volcker18, “the Federal Reserve – any central
bank – should not be asked to do too much, to undertake responsibilities that it cannot
reasonably meet with the appropriately limited powers provided.”
Amid the general recognition that more attention must be paid to financial stability
risks in the future, the key questions are: How can monetary and regulatory policies
be optimally coordinated to achieve greater financial stability? And, what is the best
institutional setup in order to safeguard central bank independence?
Capital market outlook
The Fed’s hiking cycle is likely to be closely watched, as it impacts both developed
and emerging market economies. The ECB and BoJ are expected to remain in
accommodative mode for some time yet.
With growth below the long-term trend and inflation tame, the Fed’s rate hikes are
likely to be gradual. A repeat of the 1994 bond market collapse, when the Fed’s
policy rate increased by 300 basis points in a single year, seems unlikely. The hiking
cycles in 1990–2000 and 2004–2006 are better comparisons. In 1999–2000, the
Fed raised rates by 1.5 percentage points. The Barclays Aggregate U.S. Bond Index19
lost just 0.8% in 1999 before rebounding 11.6% in 2000. In 2004–2006, the Fed
raised rates 17 times, from 1.0% to 5.25%. During those three years, the Barclays
index delivered positive returns.
An important difference, however, is that yields were higher in the two previous
episodes noted than they are today (though investment grade spreads20 were fairly
similar to today), offering more income to offset potential price declines.
The equity market’s initial reaction in all three instances was a sell-off, with the SP
500 Index ending down by an average of 3.2% after a one-month period. The average
price rise over six-month periods after the start of each rate-hiking cycle was still
positive at 2.6%. After 12 months, the average return was 6.2%, 200 basis points
below the long-term average annual price change21 (Figure 16).
Exiting monetary policy
18	 Remarks by Paul A. Volcker, May 29, 2013, “Central banking at a crossroad“
19	Formerly the Lehman Aggregate index. The index includes sovereign, quasi-sovereign and corporate
bonds
20	For US investment grade, having lost 2% in 1999, total return was 9.1% in 2000. Over 2004–2006,
the index returned 5.4%, 1.7% and 4.3% respectively
21	AAII Journal, “Don‘t Fight the Fed: Interest Rates and their Impact on the Stock Market“, Sam Stovall,
May 2009
Swiss Re Financial repression: The unintended consequences  23
In other words, rate increases and the prospect of higher interest rates have
constrained equity market rallies. Much will depend on the extent to which the US
economy can recover in the absence of stimulus and how much of the equity rally to
date has been driven by central bank liquidity. What is more certain is that market
volatility is likely to pick up, and central bank policy errors have the potential to be
more detrimental. There is a good case for seeing a different equity reaction to the
eventual tightening of rates in the current cycle.
0
4
8
12
16
12 Months
6 Months
After Rate CutsAll YearsAfter Rate Hikes
Source: SP equity research, quoted in AAII Journal, “Don’t Fight the Fed: Interest Rates and their Impact
on the Stock Market“, Sam Stovall, May 2009
Sovereign vulnerability
Higher US sovereign bond yields will lead to increased financing costs and tighter
financial conditions for many emerging market countries. Those needing to fund
large current account deficits, such as Turkey and South Africa, were shown to be
vulnerable to capital flows in May/June 2013.
However, if US sovereign bond yields increase gradually, accompanied by stronger
US growth, the shock element for emerging markets is expected to be less severe.
Markets are also more likely to differentiate between the stronger and weaker
emerging market economies. A number of these countries took steps to address
their vulnerabilities after the emerging market volatility of 2013.
Among the ‘fragile five’ emerging markets, India has been most successful in
reducing its current account deficit (Figure 17). The new government is expected to
take further steps to reduce the fiscal deficit and inflation. Brazil, Turkey and South
Africa are struggling to address their current account gap, although Brazil’s foreign
exchange reserves are significantly higher than those of Turkey and South Africa.
There are several other Latin American countries with moderately high current account
deficits, such as Peru and Chile, but their deficits are better covered by long-term
foreign direct investment (FDI) flows, and are less vulnerable to capital flight.
Figure 16:
SP 500 % changes after interest rate
hikes and cuts 1946–2008
24  Swiss Re Financial repression: The unintended consequences
Exiting monetary policy
Source: Swiss Re, Bloomberg
As the major central banks exit the ultra-accommodative policy environment, highly
indebted developed countries will become more exposed to rising financing costs.
Since the crisis, sovereign debt levels in Europe have increased significantly (Figure
18). In Spain and Ireland, sovereign debt as a percentage of GDP more than doubled
between 2007 and 2013. If growth does not pick up sufficiently to offset the rise in
financing costs, the debt sustainability of some of these countries will become more
challenging.
Source: Swiss Re, IMF WEO Database
China’s ‘exit’ from financial repression is expected to take the form of interest rate
and capital market liberalisation. This will have major repercussions for both
developed and emerging markets. Interest rate liberalisation should gradually lift
rates in China. Together with other reforms, China’s reliance on growth from
investment will likely slow over time. This will lead to lower commodity prices,
negatively impacting commodity exporters such as Australia, Chile, Peru and Brazil.
Furthermore, Asian economies that have strong trade links with mainland China,
including Hong Kong, South Korea, Taiwan and Singapore, are likely to face a
slowdown in export growth.
Figure 17:
Current account deficits among the ‘fragile
five’ countries % GDP
–9
–8
–7
–6
–5
–4
–3
–2
–1
0
Turkey South Africa India Brazil Indonesia
Sep 14Jun 14Mar 14Dec 13Sep 13Jun 13Mar 13Dec 12Sep 12Jun 12
Figure 18:
Sovereign debt (gross) as a % of GDP
0
50
100
150
200
250
2013
2007
JapanIrelandPortugalFranceItalySpainGermanyUKUS
Swiss Re Financial repression: The unintended consequences  25
While the pace of China’s capital market liberalisation is uncertain, increases in gross
capital flows will most likely be substantial. Capital account liberalisation has
historically often been followed by an exchange rate or banking crisis22. This would
have a significant impact on global financial market stability as China becomes more
integrated with global markets. For example, Figure 19 shows that UK banks’ claims
on China increased tenfold between 2005 and 2013; and are set to rise more with
further liberalisation. Loan exposures to mainland Chinese corporates by Hong Kong,
Singaporean and Taiwanese banks doubled over recent years, now standing at
27%, 9% and 6% of total banking assets23 respectively.
Source: Swiss Re, BIS Database
Figure 19:
Foreign bank claims on China (USD million),
with the UK leading the pack
0
200
400
600
800
1000
Others Taiwanese Banks Japanese Banks Australian Banks
US Banks European Banks - Others European Banks - German
European Banks - French European Banks - UK
Dec13
Dec12
Dec11
Dec10
Dec09
Dec08
Dec07
Dec06
Dec05
22	Kaminsky and Schmukler, IMF Working Paper 2003, “Short-Run Pain, Long-Run Gain: The Effect of
Financial Liberalization“, Magud, Reinhart and Vesperoni, IMF Working Paper 2012, “Capital Inflows,
Exchange Rate Flexibility, and Credit Booms“
23	UBS, February 2014, “HK/Singapore’s growing financial links to China“, BIS Database
26  Swiss Re Financial repression: The unintended consequences
Infrastructure investments and growth
Long-term investors are part of the intermediation channel that helps move saving
funds to the real economy. Keeping interest rates artificially low through public
intervention can have significant consequences on long-term investors, including
crowding out viable private markets. A healthy financial intermediation channel
is needed to sustain financial market stability and support economic growth.
Investments in infrastructure are not only growth-enhancing strategies, they also
offer attractive and suitable investment opportunities for long-term investors. With
the global economic recovery being weak by historical standards and output in
several countries lower than pre-crisis levels, the provision of long-term funds to the
economy is urgently needed. Moreover, institutional investors such as re/insurers
and pension funds require such investments to match their long-term liabilities,
as well as to improve their portfolio returns in the current low-yield environment
(see also joint Swiss Re/IIF publications24).
Assessing the impact of infrastructure investment on economic growth, two primary
channels can be identified. First, infrastructure capital increases production capacity.
Second, it may also raise productivity. In theory, both effects will lead to higher
GDP, but the magnitude of the potential increase has been debated for a long time.
Academic studies estimate that 10% more infrastructure capital can boost the long-
term GDP growth rate by 0.9 percentage points25. The IMF26 has also found that
in a low economic growth environment, USD 1 of infrastructure spending results in
almost USD 3 of additional economic output. Infrastructure investments also lower
the production costs of manufacturing firms, in turn raising their productivity27. A
recent SP study28 estimated that a USD 1.3 billion infrastructure investment would
likely add 29 000 jobs to the construction sector and USD 2 billion to US real
economic growth.
Indeed, the importance of infrastructure investment for economic growth has been
recognised globally, with the topic ranking high on the G20 agenda under the
Australian presidency.
Some USD 50–70 trillion will be needed to finance infrastructure globally through
2030. Thereby, we estimate that the current spending of roughly USD 2.6 trillion
annually will have to increase to around USD 4 trillion by 2030. This emerging
financing gap, estimated at roughly USD 1 trillion annually (also highlighted by the
WEF29), will have to be met in order to support economic growth. Though commercial
banks will remain key players, institutional investors such as re/insurers and pension
funds have a potentially much larger role to play. Infrastructure investments provide
a good balance given the steady cash flows and potential to match investors’
long-term liabilities. However, several impediments remain to unlocking the large
long-term institutional investor asset base of roughly USD 75 trillion globally. Besides
regulatory uncertainty, there is a lack of an investable and transparent asset class.
Indeed, the current infrastructure allocation of pension funds and re/insurers remains
below the average target allocation (3% vs 5%, and 2% vs 3%, respectively), as
indicated in Figure 20.
24	“Strengthening the Role of Long-term Investors“, 2013; “Infrastructure Investing. It Matters“, 2014
25	 Bom and Ligthart, CESifo working paper, January 2008
26	 IMF World Economic Outlook, October 2014
27	The American Economic Review, Morrison  Schwartz, December 1996, “State Infrastructure and
Productive Performance“
28	 SP, May 2014, “US infrastructure investment: A chance to reap more than we sow“
29	 WEF, 2014, “Infrastructure Investment Policy Blueprint“
Swiss Re Financial repression: The unintended consequences  27
Source: Investing in infrastructure: “Are insurers ready to fill the funding gap?” SP, 2014.
Note: Superannuation funds are government supported and encouraged investment funds. Here,
AustralianSuper, which is Australia‘s largest superannuation/pension fund with AUD 75 billion AuM,
is considered.
One of the challenges in bringing greater finance into infrastructure investments is,
as mentioned, the lack of a tradable asset class; this hinders depth and liquidity
within a market for infrastructure investment. Consequently, private capital market
solutions are urgently needed. A proposal for what such a solution could look like
is described in Box 5.
Figure 20:
Breakdown of average current/target
allocation to infrastructure
9
8
7
6
5
4
3
2
1
0
Insurance
company
Asset
manager
Familyoffice
Foundation
Endowment
plan
Private-sector
pensionfund
Publicpension
fund
Sovereign
wealthfund
Superannuation
scheme
%
Average current allocation to infrastructure
Average target allocation to infrastructure
28  Swiss Re Financial repression: The unintended consequences
Infrastructure investments and growth
Box 5: Swiss Re proposal to create a tradable long-term global
investment instrument
A tradable global infrastructure asset
class is needed to attract long-term
investors. Despite being well positioned
to provide long-term capital, institutional
investors require the ability to make
adjustments to their portfolios as
needed – including to their infrastruc­
ture debt holdings where, for instance,
sudden changes in the regulatory
landscape can signifi­cantly change the
risk characteristics of their investments.
As such, a tradable asset class would
unlock the long-term investor asset
base, and simultaneously also serve
as a disciplining instrument for govern­
ments when considering policy or
regulatory changes. As local infra­
structure funding needs to compete
with the more established markets,
such an asset class should be created
on a global level.
In Europe, the current EU/EIB project
bond initiative would be a good
starting point for a global model. The
EU model as well as other initiatives
(such as the Build America
Infrastructure Initiative and the World
Bank Global Infrastructure Facility)
could benefit from the following
structural elements:
i) standardised reporting and debt
documentation terms; ii) pooling of
projects; and iii) possible additional
capacity from re/insurance risk
coverage
In order to deal with the heterogeneity
of infrastructure projects, pools with
projects from similar industries could
be created, thus providing significant
diversification benefits to investors.
Consequently, there is a case for
private market participants to work
together with the public sector in
creating a “Global Project Bond
Market” and infrastructure asset class
(see graph above).
* Possibly lower central bank repo haircuts and lower regulatory capital charges due to the new features
** Pre-conditions could include: no open cession structure, alignment with risk appetite and interests
Central Banks
Long-term
investors
Standardised
Pan-regional
Projects Bonds
(“Covered
bond-like”
structure)
In blue: additional elements to
EU/EIB Project Bond Initiatives
Insurance
InvestCollateral*
Project Company 1
Project Company 2
Project Company 3
Infrastructure debt
Standardised Project
Pool with public-private
partnership (PPP)-
character. The pools can
either be a mix of both
construction and
operational phase projects,
or otherwise separated.
Truststructure
Multilateral
development
banks/
National
development
banks
(Un-)funded
credit
enhancement
of subordinated
debt
Re/insurer
Provide risk
coverage
subject to pre-
conditions**
Swiss Re Financial repression: The unintended consequences  29
Concluding remarks
30	See IMF World Economic Outlook, October 2014.
Looking ahead, financial repression is likely to remain a key tool for
policymakers given the moderate global growth outlook and high
public debt overhang. But, as outlined in this paper, financial repression
comes with significant costs. Whether the costs outweigh the benefits
largely depends on the ability of governments to take advantage of
the low interest rate environment by implementing the right structural
reforms. So far, their record for doing so has not been comforting, as
also noted by the IMF30.
Additional research on financial repression could be linked to the
impact of an aging society on the broader economic and financial
market environment and hence the optimal policy mix. Finally, a
largely unexplored area is the consequence – especially longer-term –
of public authorities acting as dominant players in their own bond
markets. How does this affect private capital markets, and how severe
are the distortions in price formation, investment decisions, allocation
to productive areas and capital flows more generally?
Swiss Re’s current work on this topic is intended to contribute to
the debate on the benefits-costs analysis and derive important
implications for sustainable policymaking that will help build stable
global capital markets. We should not wait for tomorrow to see
the effect of the policy actions taken to date. Instead, we should put
in place the elements for more stable markets today.
30  Swiss Re Financial repression: The unintended consequences
Swiss Re Financial repression: The unintended consequences  31
Unintended consequences
of financial repression include
potential asset bubbles,
a financial repression “tax”,
increasing economic
inequality, the potential of
higher inflation, and reputation
damage for central banks.
So how long will it remain a
key instrument in govern­
ments’ toolkits?
32  Swiss Re Financial repression: The unintended consequences
Appendix
Swiss Re Financial Repression Index – methodology
Notes
̤̤ Both the monetary and regulatory
components are assigned the same
index weight (ie both 43%), and the
“others” component (both regulatory
and monetary elements) has an
index weight of 14%.
̤̤ Real yields are computed for the
5Y bucket of the yield curve
̤̤ Fair values” are computed as
potential GDP growth + inflation
target of 2%. This is compared to
the 10Y government bond yield
̤̤ Taylor-rule rate = Neutral real policy
rate + core CPI + 0.5*(Inflation
target – core CPI) + 0.5*(NAIRU –
unemployment rate)
̤̤ Regulatory risk is measured using
the Swiss Re Asset Management
regulatory risk index, which is based
on i) story count of regulatory risk
in Bloomberg, and ii) the degree
of bank equity returns not being
explained by senior bank bond
spreads (the residuals in the
respective regression)
̤̤ Asset encumbrance is measured as
follows: (ECB repos + ECB lending +
Covered bonds outstanding)/total
European banking sector assets.
Currently, asset encumbrance
across Europe is around 5% based
on this methodology (which has also
been used in the October 2013 IMF
GFSR). Asset encumbrance is the
“collateral damage” of financial
repression, with regulatory reforms
“forcing” institutions to pledge more
assets, making the overall balance
sheet less flexible
̤̤ Availability of high-quality assets is
measured as the difference between
repo rate and OIS rate. An increase
in this spread indicates a scarcity in
high-quality collateral (see BIS,
2013, “Asset encumbrance,
financial reform and the demand for
collateral assets”)
̤̤ Domestic debt holdings and capital
flow consist of three variables:
i) Sovereign bonds held by domestic
banks (the “home bias”), ii) cross-
border bank claims, iii) marketable
sovereign debt (not held by central
banks)
̤̤ Data frequency: In general, most
data used for the index is available
either on a monthly or more frequent
basis. The exception is the
‘availability of high-quality liquid
assets’ and the ‘other component’,
where some data is only available
on an annual basis
̤̤ Regional reach: Most components
represent an average for the EU and
the US. Asset encumbrance and
high-quality liquid assets have a
European focus only
̤̤ Data sources are Bloomberg, ECB,
OECD, Bruegel and BIS
Current level –1 year –5 years
Overall index (sum of component contributors) 4.2 4.1 2.5
1. Real govt. bond yields 0.10 0.10 0.00
2. Difference actual yields vs. “fair value“ 0.65 0.45 0.10
3. Central bank asset purchases 0.35 0.40 0.05
4. Difference policy rate vs. “Taylor rule“ 0.75 0.60 0.20
5. Regulatory risk 0.90 0.90 0.50
6. Asset encumbrance 0.20 0.50 0.40
7. Availability of high-quality liquid assets 0.45 0.35 0.75
8. Domestic debts holdings and capital flows 0.75 0.75 0.55
Monetary
components
Regulatory
components
“Others“
Source: Swiss Re
© 2015 Swiss Re. All rights reserved.
Title:
Financial repression:
The unintended consequences
Authors:
Jérôme Haegeli
Chuan Lim
Tauno Loertscher
Laurent Degoumois
Steven Biekens
Editing and realisation:
Katharina Fehr
Cushla Sherlock
Managing editor:
Urs Leimbacher
Graphic design and production:
Corporate Real Estate  Logistics/
Media Production, Zurich
Printing:
Corporate Real Estate  Logistics/
Media Production, Zurich
Disclaimer: The content of this brochure is subject
to copyright with all rights reserved. The information
may be used for private or internal purposes,
provided that any copyright or other proprietary
notices are not removed. Electronic reuse of the
content of this brochure is prohibited. Reproduction
in whole or in part or use for any public purpose
is only permitted with the prior written approval of
Swiss Re, and if the source reference is indicated.
Courtesy copies are appreciated.
Swiss Re gives no advice and makes no investment
recommendation to buy, sell or otherwise deal in
securities or investments whatsoever. This document
does not constitute an invitation to effect any
transaction in securities or make investments.
Although all the information used was taken from
reliable sources, Swiss Re does not accept any res-
ponsibility for the accuracy or comprehensiveness
of the details given. All liability for the accuracy and
completeness thereof or for any damage resulting
from the use of the information contained in this
brochure is expressly excluded. Under no circum-
stances shall Swiss Re or its Group companies
be liable for any financial and/or consequential loss
relating to this brochure.
Order no: 1506050_15_en
02/15, 1 000 en
Swiss Reinsurance Company Ltd
Mythenquai 50/60
P.O. Box
8022 Zurich
Switzerland
Telephone +41 43 285 2121
Fax +41 43 285 2999
www.swissre.com

More Related Content

What's hot

Stagflation
StagflationStagflation
trends in national income growth and structure
trends in national income growth and structure trends in national income growth and structure
trends in national income growth and structure
Sweata Yadav
 
Presentation on inflation
Presentation on inflationPresentation on inflation
Presentation on inflationVikram g b
 
Effect of recession ppt
Effect of recession pptEffect of recession ppt
Effect of recession ppt
rashmi_1214
 
External debt of india
External debt of indiaExternal debt of india
External debt of india
Saloni Sanghani
 
Inflation powerpoint
Inflation powerpointInflation powerpoint
Inflation powerpointGerard1990
 
Pakistan government debt
Pakistan government debtPakistan government debt
Pakistan government debt
ShahWazir1
 
Inflation
Inflation Inflation
Inflation
Varsha-sharma
 
Monetary Policy Of Pakistan 2013-14
Monetary Policy Of Pakistan 2013-14Monetary Policy Of Pakistan 2013-14
Monetary Policy Of Pakistan 2013-14Jawad Ahmed
 
Measures to control inflation
Measures to control inflationMeasures to control inflation
Measures to control inflation
Raviinder Ahluwalia
 
Inflation, deflation,stagflation, reinflation,disinflation
Inflation, deflation,stagflation, reinflation,disinflationInflation, deflation,stagflation, reinflation,disinflation
Inflation, deflation,stagflation, reinflation,disinflation
Nauman Hassan
 
Inflation In India
Inflation In IndiaInflation In India
Inflation In Indiaguest4378e8f
 
Presentation On Inflation
Presentation On InflationPresentation On Inflation
Presentation On Inflation
Rizwan Khan
 
Consequences of Financial Crises
Consequences of Financial CrisesConsequences of Financial Crises
Consequences of Financial Crises
tutor2u
 
Monetary Policy Effectiveness of monetary policy to combat inflation: India e...
Monetary Policy Effectiveness of monetary policy to combat inflation: India e...Monetary Policy Effectiveness of monetary policy to combat inflation: India e...
Monetary Policy Effectiveness of monetary policy to combat inflation: India e...
MD SALMAN ANJUM
 
Transmission Mechanism of Monetary Policy
Transmission Mechanism of Monetary PolicyTransmission Mechanism of Monetary Policy
Transmission Mechanism of Monetary Policy
AmandiNiwarthanaWeer
 
Fiscal Responsibility and Budget Management
Fiscal Responsibility and Budget ManagementFiscal Responsibility and Budget Management
Fiscal Responsibility and Budget Management
Paras Savla
 

What's hot (20)

Stagflation
StagflationStagflation
Stagflation
 
Inflation
InflationInflation
Inflation
 
trends in national income growth and structure
trends in national income growth and structure trends in national income growth and structure
trends in national income growth and structure
 
Presentation on inflation
Presentation on inflationPresentation on inflation
Presentation on inflation
 
Effect of recession ppt
Effect of recession pptEffect of recession ppt
Effect of recession ppt
 
External debt of india
External debt of indiaExternal debt of india
External debt of india
 
Inflation powerpoint
Inflation powerpointInflation powerpoint
Inflation powerpoint
 
Pakistan government debt
Pakistan government debtPakistan government debt
Pakistan government debt
 
Inflation
Inflation Inflation
Inflation
 
Monetary Policy Of Pakistan 2013-14
Monetary Policy Of Pakistan 2013-14Monetary Policy Of Pakistan 2013-14
Monetary Policy Of Pakistan 2013-14
 
Measures to control inflation
Measures to control inflationMeasures to control inflation
Measures to control inflation
 
Inflation, deflation,stagflation, reinflation,disinflation
Inflation, deflation,stagflation, reinflation,disinflationInflation, deflation,stagflation, reinflation,disinflation
Inflation, deflation,stagflation, reinflation,disinflation
 
Inflation In India
Inflation In IndiaInflation In India
Inflation In India
 
Presentation On Inflation
Presentation On InflationPresentation On Inflation
Presentation On Inflation
 
Consequences of Financial Crises
Consequences of Financial CrisesConsequences of Financial Crises
Consequences of Financial Crises
 
Monetary Policy Effectiveness of monetary policy to combat inflation: India e...
Monetary Policy Effectiveness of monetary policy to combat inflation: India e...Monetary Policy Effectiveness of monetary policy to combat inflation: India e...
Monetary Policy Effectiveness of monetary policy to combat inflation: India e...
 
Transmission Mechanism of Monetary Policy
Transmission Mechanism of Monetary PolicyTransmission Mechanism of Monetary Policy
Transmission Mechanism of Monetary Policy
 
Inflation
InflationInflation
Inflation
 
Fiscal Responsibility and Budget Management
Fiscal Responsibility and Budget ManagementFiscal Responsibility and Budget Management
Fiscal Responsibility and Budget Management
 
Fiscal deficit
Fiscal deficitFiscal deficit
Fiscal deficit
 

Similar to Financial Repression

To the Point - 2010, November
To the Point - 2010, NovemberTo the Point - 2010, November
To the Point - 2010, November
Swedbank
 
To the Point, 2010 March
To the Point, 2010 MarchTo the Point, 2010 March
To the Point, 2010 March
Swedbank
 
To the Point, 2010, March 30
To the Point, 2010, March 30To the Point, 2010, March 30
To the Point, 2010, March 30
Swedbank
 
IMF: Global Financial Stability Report (April 2020)
IMF: Global Financial Stability Report (April 2020)IMF: Global Financial Stability Report (April 2020)
IMF: Global Financial Stability Report (April 2020)
TatianaApostolovich
 
A Checklist for Wanna-be Helicopter Pilots
A Checklist for Wanna-be Helicopter PilotsA Checklist for Wanna-be Helicopter Pilots
A Checklist for Wanna-be Helicopter PilotsAndrea Iannelli
 
MTBiz September 2014
MTBiz September 2014MTBiz September 2014
MTBiz September 2014
Mutual Trust Bank Ltd.
 
What Is Monetary Policy?: Unlock The 2 Important Types Of It Compare Closing LLC
What Is Monetary Policy?: Unlock The 2 Important Types Of It Compare Closing LLCWhat Is Monetary Policy?: Unlock The 2 Important Types Of It Compare Closing LLC
What Is Monetary Policy?: Unlock The 2 Important Types Of It Compare Closing LLC
CompareClosing
 
What recent and past actions have Canada and the US taken to counter.pdf
What recent and past actions have Canada and the US taken to counter.pdfWhat recent and past actions have Canada and the US taken to counter.pdf
What recent and past actions have Canada and the US taken to counter.pdf
meejuhaszjasmynspe52
 
EIU Global Forecast Report Q4/2020
EIU Global Forecast Report Q4/2020EIU Global Forecast Report Q4/2020
EIU Global Forecast Report Q4/2020
Muniruddeen Lallmahamood (Dr.)
 
12 bad banks_finding_the_right_exit_from_the_financial_crisis
12 bad banks_finding_the_right_exit_from_the_financial_crisis12 bad banks_finding_the_right_exit_from_the_financial_crisis
12 bad banks_finding_the_right_exit_from_the_financial_crisis
Fachry Frisandi
 
Monetary and fiscal policy response and recent developments
Monetary and fiscal policy response and recent developmentsMonetary and fiscal policy response and recent developments
Monetary and fiscal policy response and recent developmentsClaro Ganac
 
1. GLOBAL IMBALANCES1.1 Cheap But Flighty How Global Imbalanc.docx
1. GLOBAL IMBALANCES1.1 Cheap But Flighty How Global Imbalanc.docx1. GLOBAL IMBALANCES1.1 Cheap But Flighty How Global Imbalanc.docx
1. GLOBAL IMBALANCES1.1 Cheap But Flighty How Global Imbalanc.docx
SONU61709
 
Recent development
Recent developmentRecent development
Recent developmentnileshsen
 
Building Business Resilience and Ingenuity
Building Business Resilience and IngenuityBuilding Business Resilience and Ingenuity
Building Business Resilience and IngenuitySubramanya Raja .V
 
economic group assinment.pdf
economic group assinment.pdfeconomic group assinment.pdf
economic group assinment.pdf
FazilatShahid
 
All bound up? Monetary policy in recovery and beyond
All bound up? Monetary policy in recovery and beyondAll bound up? Monetary policy in recovery and beyond
All bound up? Monetary policy in recovery and beyond
ResolutionFoundation
 
AnsA) When financial markets stood on the verge of collapse in th.pdf
AnsA) When financial markets stood on the verge of collapse in th.pdfAnsA) When financial markets stood on the verge of collapse in th.pdf
AnsA) When financial markets stood on the verge of collapse in th.pdf
sutharbharat59
 
A Macroeconomic Framework for Growth Under “The New Normal”
A Macroeconomic Framework for Growth Under “The New Normal”A Macroeconomic Framework for Growth Under “The New Normal”
A Macroeconomic Framework for Growth Under “The New Normal”
Economic Research Forum
 
UCMP.pptx
UCMP.pptxUCMP.pptx
UCMP.pptx
RishavRaj752309
 

Similar to Financial Repression (20)

To the Point - 2010, November
To the Point - 2010, NovemberTo the Point - 2010, November
To the Point - 2010, November
 
To the Point, 2010 March
To the Point, 2010 MarchTo the Point, 2010 March
To the Point, 2010 March
 
To the Point, 2010, March 30
To the Point, 2010, March 30To the Point, 2010, March 30
To the Point, 2010, March 30
 
IMF: Global Financial Stability Report (April 2020)
IMF: Global Financial Stability Report (April 2020)IMF: Global Financial Stability Report (April 2020)
IMF: Global Financial Stability Report (April 2020)
 
A Checklist for Wanna-be Helicopter Pilots
A Checklist for Wanna-be Helicopter PilotsA Checklist for Wanna-be Helicopter Pilots
A Checklist for Wanna-be Helicopter Pilots
 
MTBiz September 2014
MTBiz September 2014MTBiz September 2014
MTBiz September 2014
 
What Is Monetary Policy?: Unlock The 2 Important Types Of It Compare Closing LLC
What Is Monetary Policy?: Unlock The 2 Important Types Of It Compare Closing LLCWhat Is Monetary Policy?: Unlock The 2 Important Types Of It Compare Closing LLC
What Is Monetary Policy?: Unlock The 2 Important Types Of It Compare Closing LLC
 
What recent and past actions have Canada and the US taken to counter.pdf
What recent and past actions have Canada and the US taken to counter.pdfWhat recent and past actions have Canada and the US taken to counter.pdf
What recent and past actions have Canada and the US taken to counter.pdf
 
EIU Global Forecast Report Q4/2020
EIU Global Forecast Report Q4/2020EIU Global Forecast Report Q4/2020
EIU Global Forecast Report Q4/2020
 
12 bad banks_finding_the_right_exit_from_the_financial_crisis
12 bad banks_finding_the_right_exit_from_the_financial_crisis12 bad banks_finding_the_right_exit_from_the_financial_crisis
12 bad banks_finding_the_right_exit_from_the_financial_crisis
 
Monetary and fiscal policy response and recent developments
Monetary and fiscal policy response and recent developmentsMonetary and fiscal policy response and recent developments
Monetary and fiscal policy response and recent developments
 
1. GLOBAL IMBALANCES1.1 Cheap But Flighty How Global Imbalanc.docx
1. GLOBAL IMBALANCES1.1 Cheap But Flighty How Global Imbalanc.docx1. GLOBAL IMBALANCES1.1 Cheap But Flighty How Global Imbalanc.docx
1. GLOBAL IMBALANCES1.1 Cheap But Flighty How Global Imbalanc.docx
 
Recent development
Recent developmentRecent development
Recent development
 
Download
DownloadDownload
Download
 
Building Business Resilience and Ingenuity
Building Business Resilience and IngenuityBuilding Business Resilience and Ingenuity
Building Business Resilience and Ingenuity
 
economic group assinment.pdf
economic group assinment.pdfeconomic group assinment.pdf
economic group assinment.pdf
 
All bound up? Monetary policy in recovery and beyond
All bound up? Monetary policy in recovery and beyondAll bound up? Monetary policy in recovery and beyond
All bound up? Monetary policy in recovery and beyond
 
AnsA) When financial markets stood on the verge of collapse in th.pdf
AnsA) When financial markets stood on the verge of collapse in th.pdfAnsA) When financial markets stood on the verge of collapse in th.pdf
AnsA) When financial markets stood on the verge of collapse in th.pdf
 
A Macroeconomic Framework for Growth Under “The New Normal”
A Macroeconomic Framework for Growth Under “The New Normal”A Macroeconomic Framework for Growth Under “The New Normal”
A Macroeconomic Framework for Growth Under “The New Normal”
 
UCMP.pptx
UCMP.pptxUCMP.pptx
UCMP.pptx
 

More from Luis Taveras EMBA, MS

Where is Our Government? Part II
Where is Our Government? Part IIWhere is Our Government? Part II
Where is Our Government? Part II
Luis Taveras EMBA, MS
 
Leadership Academy _Audit
Leadership Academy _AuditLeadership Academy _Audit
Leadership Academy _Audit
Luis Taveras EMBA, MS
 
NYC DOE's Overssight of Computer Hardware Purchased
NYC DOE's Overssight of Computer Hardware PurchasedNYC DOE's Overssight of Computer Hardware Purchased
NYC DOE's Overssight of Computer Hardware Purchased
Luis Taveras EMBA, MS
 
How NYC'S Pension Costs Threaten Its Future
How NYC'S Pension Costs Threaten Its FutureHow NYC'S Pension Costs Threaten Its Future
How NYC'S Pension Costs Threaten Its Future
Luis Taveras EMBA, MS
 
American Competitiveness Initiative:Leading the World in Innovation aci06-b...
American Competitiveness Initiative:Leading the World in Innovation   aci06-b...American Competitiveness Initiative:Leading the World in Innovation   aci06-b...
American Competitiveness Initiative:Leading the World in Innovation aci06-b...
Luis Taveras EMBA, MS
 
NYC PENSION COST
NYC PENSION COST NYC PENSION COST
NYC PENSION COST
Luis Taveras EMBA, MS
 
The Latino Effect on Economic Growth
The Latino Effect on Economic Growth The Latino Effect on Economic Growth
The Latino Effect on Economic Growth
Luis Taveras EMBA, MS
 
AUDIT REPORT OF SUCCESS ACADEMY CHARTER SCHOOLS
AUDIT REPORT OF SUCCESS ACADEMY CHARTER SCHOOLSAUDIT REPORT OF SUCCESS ACADEMY CHARTER SCHOOLS
AUDIT REPORT OF SUCCESS ACADEMY CHARTER SCHOOLS
Luis Taveras EMBA, MS
 
Investigation of The City University of New York
Investigation of The City University of New York Investigation of The City University of New York
Investigation of The City University of New York
Luis Taveras EMBA, MS
 
Optimization with an Impact (OpIm)
Optimization with an Impact (OpIm)Optimization with an Impact (OpIm)
Optimization with an Impact (OpIm)
Luis Taveras EMBA, MS
 
Global Pensions Asset Study 2016
Global Pensions Asset Study 2016Global Pensions Asset Study 2016
Global Pensions Asset Study 2016
Luis Taveras EMBA, MS
 
The Securities Industry in New York City
The Securities Industry in New York CityThe Securities Industry in New York City
The Securities Industry in New York City
Luis Taveras EMBA, MS
 
References
ReferencesReferences
School Finance_Traditional vs. Charter Schools
School Finance_Traditional vs. Charter SchoolsSchool Finance_Traditional vs. Charter Schools
School Finance_Traditional vs. Charter Schools
Luis Taveras EMBA, MS
 
The Educational Impact of Broadband Sudsidies for Schools Under ERate
The Educational Impact of Broadband Sudsidies for Schools Under ERateThe Educational Impact of Broadband Sudsidies for Schools Under ERate
The Educational Impact of Broadband Sudsidies for Schools Under ERate
Luis Taveras EMBA, MS
 
I don't want to see homeless riff raff
I don't want to see homeless riff raff I don't want to see homeless riff raff
I don't want to see homeless riff raff
Luis Taveras EMBA, MS
 
High-Tech Employees "No Poach" Antitrust Litigation
High-Tech Employees "No Poach" Antitrust LitigationHigh-Tech Employees "No Poach" Antitrust Litigation
High-Tech Employees "No Poach" Antitrust Litigation
Luis Taveras EMBA, MS
 
How Apple Sidesteps Billions in Taxes
How Apple Sidesteps Billions in TaxesHow Apple Sidesteps Billions in Taxes
How Apple Sidesteps Billions in Taxes
Luis Taveras EMBA, MS
 
Gleevec
GleevecGleevec

More from Luis Taveras EMBA, MS (20)

Where is Our Government? Part II
Where is Our Government? Part IIWhere is Our Government? Part II
Where is Our Government? Part II
 
Leadership Academy _Audit
Leadership Academy _AuditLeadership Academy _Audit
Leadership Academy _Audit
 
NYC DOE's Overssight of Computer Hardware Purchased
NYC DOE's Overssight of Computer Hardware PurchasedNYC DOE's Overssight of Computer Hardware Purchased
NYC DOE's Overssight of Computer Hardware Purchased
 
How NYC'S Pension Costs Threaten Its Future
How NYC'S Pension Costs Threaten Its FutureHow NYC'S Pension Costs Threaten Its Future
How NYC'S Pension Costs Threaten Its Future
 
American Competitiveness Initiative:Leading the World in Innovation aci06-b...
American Competitiveness Initiative:Leading the World in Innovation   aci06-b...American Competitiveness Initiative:Leading the World in Innovation   aci06-b...
American Competitiveness Initiative:Leading the World in Innovation aci06-b...
 
NYC PENSION COST
NYC PENSION COST NYC PENSION COST
NYC PENSION COST
 
The Latino Effect on Economic Growth
The Latino Effect on Economic Growth The Latino Effect on Economic Growth
The Latino Effect on Economic Growth
 
AUDIT REPORT OF SUCCESS ACADEMY CHARTER SCHOOLS
AUDIT REPORT OF SUCCESS ACADEMY CHARTER SCHOOLSAUDIT REPORT OF SUCCESS ACADEMY CHARTER SCHOOLS
AUDIT REPORT OF SUCCESS ACADEMY CHARTER SCHOOLS
 
PresentationtoCD
PresentationtoCDPresentationtoCD
PresentationtoCD
 
Investigation of The City University of New York
Investigation of The City University of New York Investigation of The City University of New York
Investigation of The City University of New York
 
Optimization with an Impact (OpIm)
Optimization with an Impact (OpIm)Optimization with an Impact (OpIm)
Optimization with an Impact (OpIm)
 
Global Pensions Asset Study 2016
Global Pensions Asset Study 2016Global Pensions Asset Study 2016
Global Pensions Asset Study 2016
 
The Securities Industry in New York City
The Securities Industry in New York CityThe Securities Industry in New York City
The Securities Industry in New York City
 
References
ReferencesReferences
References
 
School Finance_Traditional vs. Charter Schools
School Finance_Traditional vs. Charter SchoolsSchool Finance_Traditional vs. Charter Schools
School Finance_Traditional vs. Charter Schools
 
The Educational Impact of Broadband Sudsidies for Schools Under ERate
The Educational Impact of Broadband Sudsidies for Schools Under ERateThe Educational Impact of Broadband Sudsidies for Schools Under ERate
The Educational Impact of Broadband Sudsidies for Schools Under ERate
 
I don't want to see homeless riff raff
I don't want to see homeless riff raff I don't want to see homeless riff raff
I don't want to see homeless riff raff
 
High-Tech Employees "No Poach" Antitrust Litigation
High-Tech Employees "No Poach" Antitrust LitigationHigh-Tech Employees "No Poach" Antitrust Litigation
High-Tech Employees "No Poach" Antitrust Litigation
 
How Apple Sidesteps Billions in Taxes
How Apple Sidesteps Billions in TaxesHow Apple Sidesteps Billions in Taxes
How Apple Sidesteps Billions in Taxes
 
Gleevec
GleevecGleevec
Gleevec
 

Recently uploaded

when will pi network coin be available on crypto exchange.
when will pi network coin be available on crypto exchange.when will pi network coin be available on crypto exchange.
when will pi network coin be available on crypto exchange.
DOT TECH
 
APP I Lecture Notes to students 0f 4the year
APP I  Lecture Notes  to students 0f 4the yearAPP I  Lecture Notes  to students 0f 4the year
APP I Lecture Notes to students 0f 4the year
telilaalilemlem
 
PF-Wagner's Theory of Public Expenditure.pptx
PF-Wagner's Theory of Public Expenditure.pptxPF-Wagner's Theory of Public Expenditure.pptx
PF-Wagner's Theory of Public Expenditure.pptx
GunjanSharma28848
 
BYD SWOT Analysis and In-Depth Insights 2024.pptx
BYD SWOT Analysis and In-Depth Insights 2024.pptxBYD SWOT Analysis and In-Depth Insights 2024.pptx
BYD SWOT Analysis and In-Depth Insights 2024.pptx
mikemetalprod
 
managementaccountingunitiv-230422140105-dd17d80b.ppt
managementaccountingunitiv-230422140105-dd17d80b.pptmanagementaccountingunitiv-230422140105-dd17d80b.ppt
managementaccountingunitiv-230422140105-dd17d80b.ppt
SuseelaPalanimuthu
 
how can i use my minded pi coins I need some funds.
how can i use my minded pi coins I need some funds.how can i use my minded pi coins I need some funds.
how can i use my minded pi coins I need some funds.
DOT TECH
 
This assessment plan proposal is to outline a structured approach to evaluati...
This assessment plan proposal is to outline a structured approach to evaluati...This assessment plan proposal is to outline a structured approach to evaluati...
This assessment plan proposal is to outline a structured approach to evaluati...
lamluanvan.net Viết thuê luận văn
 
The Evolution of Non-Banking Financial Companies (NBFCs) in India: Challenges...
The Evolution of Non-Banking Financial Companies (NBFCs) in India: Challenges...The Evolution of Non-Banking Financial Companies (NBFCs) in India: Challenges...
The Evolution of Non-Banking Financial Companies (NBFCs) in India: Challenges...
beulahfernandes8
 
What price will pi network be listed on exchanges
What price will pi network be listed on exchangesWhat price will pi network be listed on exchanges
What price will pi network be listed on exchanges
DOT TECH
 
What website can I sell pi coins securely.
What website can I sell pi coins securely.What website can I sell pi coins securely.
What website can I sell pi coins securely.
DOT TECH
 
Webinar Exploring DORA for Fintechs - Simont Braun
Webinar Exploring DORA for Fintechs - Simont BraunWebinar Exploring DORA for Fintechs - Simont Braun
Webinar Exploring DORA for Fintechs - Simont Braun
FinTech Belgium
 
Isios-2024-Professional-Independent-Trustee-Survey.pdf
Isios-2024-Professional-Independent-Trustee-Survey.pdfIsios-2024-Professional-Independent-Trustee-Survey.pdf
Isios-2024-Professional-Independent-Trustee-Survey.pdf
Henry Tapper
 
what is a pi whale and how to access one.
what is a pi whale and how to access one.what is a pi whale and how to access one.
what is a pi whale and how to access one.
DOT TECH
 
innovative-invoice-discounting-platforms-in-india-empowering-retail-investors...
innovative-invoice-discounting-platforms-in-india-empowering-retail-investors...innovative-invoice-discounting-platforms-in-india-empowering-retail-investors...
innovative-invoice-discounting-platforms-in-india-empowering-retail-investors...
Falcon Invoice Discounting
 
The new type of smart, sustainable entrepreneurship and the next day | Europe...
The new type of smart, sustainable entrepreneurship and the next day | Europe...The new type of smart, sustainable entrepreneurship and the next day | Europe...
The new type of smart, sustainable entrepreneurship and the next day | Europe...
Antonis Zairis
 
where can I find a legit pi merchant online
where can I find a legit pi merchant onlinewhere can I find a legit pi merchant online
where can I find a legit pi merchant online
DOT TECH
 
Financial Assets: Debit vs Equity Securities.pptx
Financial Assets: Debit vs Equity Securities.pptxFinancial Assets: Debit vs Equity Securities.pptx
Financial Assets: Debit vs Equity Securities.pptx
Writo-Finance
 
how to sell pi coins on Bitmart crypto exchange
how to sell pi coins on Bitmart crypto exchangehow to sell pi coins on Bitmart crypto exchange
how to sell pi coins on Bitmart crypto exchange
DOT TECH
 
US Economic Outlook - Being Decided - M Capital Group August 2021.pdf
US Economic Outlook - Being Decided - M Capital Group August 2021.pdfUS Economic Outlook - Being Decided - M Capital Group August 2021.pdf
US Economic Outlook - Being Decided - M Capital Group August 2021.pdf
pchutichetpong
 
Commercial Bank Economic Capsule - May 2024
Commercial Bank Economic Capsule - May 2024Commercial Bank Economic Capsule - May 2024
Commercial Bank Economic Capsule - May 2024
Commercial Bank of Ceylon PLC
 

Recently uploaded (20)

when will pi network coin be available on crypto exchange.
when will pi network coin be available on crypto exchange.when will pi network coin be available on crypto exchange.
when will pi network coin be available on crypto exchange.
 
APP I Lecture Notes to students 0f 4the year
APP I  Lecture Notes  to students 0f 4the yearAPP I  Lecture Notes  to students 0f 4the year
APP I Lecture Notes to students 0f 4the year
 
PF-Wagner's Theory of Public Expenditure.pptx
PF-Wagner's Theory of Public Expenditure.pptxPF-Wagner's Theory of Public Expenditure.pptx
PF-Wagner's Theory of Public Expenditure.pptx
 
BYD SWOT Analysis and In-Depth Insights 2024.pptx
BYD SWOT Analysis and In-Depth Insights 2024.pptxBYD SWOT Analysis and In-Depth Insights 2024.pptx
BYD SWOT Analysis and In-Depth Insights 2024.pptx
 
managementaccountingunitiv-230422140105-dd17d80b.ppt
managementaccountingunitiv-230422140105-dd17d80b.pptmanagementaccountingunitiv-230422140105-dd17d80b.ppt
managementaccountingunitiv-230422140105-dd17d80b.ppt
 
how can i use my minded pi coins I need some funds.
how can i use my minded pi coins I need some funds.how can i use my minded pi coins I need some funds.
how can i use my minded pi coins I need some funds.
 
This assessment plan proposal is to outline a structured approach to evaluati...
This assessment plan proposal is to outline a structured approach to evaluati...This assessment plan proposal is to outline a structured approach to evaluati...
This assessment plan proposal is to outline a structured approach to evaluati...
 
The Evolution of Non-Banking Financial Companies (NBFCs) in India: Challenges...
The Evolution of Non-Banking Financial Companies (NBFCs) in India: Challenges...The Evolution of Non-Banking Financial Companies (NBFCs) in India: Challenges...
The Evolution of Non-Banking Financial Companies (NBFCs) in India: Challenges...
 
What price will pi network be listed on exchanges
What price will pi network be listed on exchangesWhat price will pi network be listed on exchanges
What price will pi network be listed on exchanges
 
What website can I sell pi coins securely.
What website can I sell pi coins securely.What website can I sell pi coins securely.
What website can I sell pi coins securely.
 
Webinar Exploring DORA for Fintechs - Simont Braun
Webinar Exploring DORA for Fintechs - Simont BraunWebinar Exploring DORA for Fintechs - Simont Braun
Webinar Exploring DORA for Fintechs - Simont Braun
 
Isios-2024-Professional-Independent-Trustee-Survey.pdf
Isios-2024-Professional-Independent-Trustee-Survey.pdfIsios-2024-Professional-Independent-Trustee-Survey.pdf
Isios-2024-Professional-Independent-Trustee-Survey.pdf
 
what is a pi whale and how to access one.
what is a pi whale and how to access one.what is a pi whale and how to access one.
what is a pi whale and how to access one.
 
innovative-invoice-discounting-platforms-in-india-empowering-retail-investors...
innovative-invoice-discounting-platforms-in-india-empowering-retail-investors...innovative-invoice-discounting-platforms-in-india-empowering-retail-investors...
innovative-invoice-discounting-platforms-in-india-empowering-retail-investors...
 
The new type of smart, sustainable entrepreneurship and the next day | Europe...
The new type of smart, sustainable entrepreneurship and the next day | Europe...The new type of smart, sustainable entrepreneurship and the next day | Europe...
The new type of smart, sustainable entrepreneurship and the next day | Europe...
 
where can I find a legit pi merchant online
where can I find a legit pi merchant onlinewhere can I find a legit pi merchant online
where can I find a legit pi merchant online
 
Financial Assets: Debit vs Equity Securities.pptx
Financial Assets: Debit vs Equity Securities.pptxFinancial Assets: Debit vs Equity Securities.pptx
Financial Assets: Debit vs Equity Securities.pptx
 
how to sell pi coins on Bitmart crypto exchange
how to sell pi coins on Bitmart crypto exchangehow to sell pi coins on Bitmart crypto exchange
how to sell pi coins on Bitmart crypto exchange
 
US Economic Outlook - Being Decided - M Capital Group August 2021.pdf
US Economic Outlook - Being Decided - M Capital Group August 2021.pdfUS Economic Outlook - Being Decided - M Capital Group August 2021.pdf
US Economic Outlook - Being Decided - M Capital Group August 2021.pdf
 
Commercial Bank Economic Capsule - May 2024
Commercial Bank Economic Capsule - May 2024Commercial Bank Economic Capsule - May 2024
Commercial Bank Economic Capsule - May 2024
 

Financial Repression

  • 1. Unconventional monetary policies help to finance the public sector’s debt burden. While a number of these policies were crucial and beneficial to managing the financial crisis, they also come with significant costs. The unintended consequences include potential asset price bubbles, an impaired credit intermediation channel and increasing economic inequality. Financial repression: The unintended consequences
  • 2. Today’s low interest rate environment is not only driven by macroeconomic factors, but also by policy actions that help governments deal with the high sovereign debt burden. These policies – called “financial repression” – have unintended consequences for both households and long-term investors like insurance companies or pension funds.
  • 3. Foreword Central banks have done an extraordinarily good job of stabilising financial markets, restoring economic confidence and fighting the threat of deflation – no question about that. But seven years after the financial crisis, interest rates are still being kept at historically low levels, mainly due to the ongoing low growth environment. Do low interest rates really help to overcome the global economic malaise? Doubts abound. They certainly do have one effect: That is, helping governments to direct funds to themselves to finance their debt and lower their funding costs – a set of policies known as financial repression. Indeed, policymakers’ actions to manage the financial crisis resulted in significant benefits for society at large. But today, the advantages of those ongoing actions are outweighed by their costs. As well as resulting in lower interest earnings on savings, financial repression serves as a disincentive for policymakers to tackle pressing public policy challenges and thus advance the structural reform agenda. Furthermore, continued intervention by policymakers calls into question the existence and independence of markets more generally. Central bank financial market engineering is no substitute for economic reforms. Swiss Re has developed its own index to track financial repression. This publication contributes to quantifying its costs. We want to weigh in on today’s key public policy debate, adding valuable insight into the unintended consequences of financial repression and preserving the important opportunities for long-term investors. Guido Fürer Group Chief Investment Officer Swiss Re
  • 4. 2  Swiss Re Financial repression: The unintended consequences
  • 5. Table of contents   Introduction 4 Overview of global monetary policy 6 Unintended consequences of financial repression 10 Asset price bubbles 10 Impact on private households 13 Impact on institutional investors 17 Inflation and credibility 19 Exiting monetary policy 22 Capital market outlook 22 Sovereign vulnerability 23 Infrastructure investments and growth 26 Concluding remarks 29 Appendix 32
  • 6. 4  Swiss Re Financial repression: The unintended consequences Introduction The costs of financial repression are significant. Since the financial crisis, US savers alone have lost roughly USD 470 billion in interest rate income, net of lower debt costs. The policy is not only supported by central banks’ actions, but also by regulatory rules that favour sovereign bonds. Today’s low interest rate environment is not only driven by macroeconomic factors, but foremost by policy actions that help governments deal with the high sovereign debt burden. Regulatory rules that support financial repression by favouring sovereign bonds have also been put in place. The impact of financial repression on markets, so far, is undisputable: Continued increases in bond prices, expensive stocks and relatively low volatility – a situation which is hardly sustainable. Moreover, the policy actions that cause financial repression entail a number of unintended consequences (see page 10). These include potential asset price bubbles, convergence in asset allocation strategies of otherwise heterogeneous financial market participants and an increase in economic inequality. With regards to the latter, the impact of foregone interest income for households and long-term investors is substantial. At the same time, the equity rally has predominantly benefited society’s wealthiest. Furthermore, central bank independence and credibility is increasingly questioned. The longer such extraordinary and unconventional monetary policies are in place following the move from crisis management to crisis resolution, the more challenging the “exit phase” will be (see page 22). The costs of financial repression are significant. Let’s take the US as an example. Had the Federal Reserve (Fed) followed a policy based on the Taylor rule1, the interest rate target would have been roughly 1.7 percentage points higher on average than it was in the period 2008–2013. When also taking into account longer-term rates (and their extent of being below their “fair equilibrium value”) and the lower debt- related expenditures for households, the net tax on US savers amounts to USD 470 billion of foregone interest rates over that period. Simultaneously, wealthier savers benefited from the equity rally, bringing along new issues related to economic inequality. Box 1 shows the cumulative effect in the US since the financial crisis. 1 Taylor-rule rate = Neutral real policy rate + core CPI + 0.5*(Inflation target – core CPI) + 0.5* (NAIRU – unemployment rate)
  • 7. Swiss Re Financial repression: The unintended consequences  5 Without a doubt, the legacy of the crisis – highly leveraged economies – is still present today. But resolving this legacy issue with continued application of past interventionist instruments does not incentivise the much needed structural reforms and private capital market activities. Financial repression has induced a re-allocation of capital across markets and greatly enhanced the role of public markets at the detriment of private market activities. Artificially low – or in some cases even negative – interest rates break the credit intermediation channel which can crowd out viable private investors. This lowers their ability to channel funds to the real economy. Today’s broken intermediation channel needs to be repaired durably. For that, more private capital market solutions are required. Investments in infrastructure (see page 26) serve as growth-enhancing strategies that could repair some of this damage, especially if financed by the private sector and traded in private capital markets. The following sections provide an overview of global monetary policy and analyse the unintended consequences of financial repression. Additionally, central bank policy “exit” is reviewed in the context of the capital market outlook and sovereign vulnerability. Finally, infrastructure investments are outlined as a means of addressing the broken credit intermediation channel and weak economic growth. USD 8tn USD 3tn USD 500bn USD 1tn USD 400bn USD 2tn USD 9tn Foregone US households’ interest income net of lower debt costs Box1: Cumulative since the global financial crisis
  • 8. 6  Swiss Re Financial repression: The unintended consequences Overview of global monetary policy In the aftermath of the 2008–2009 global financial crisis, central banks around the world undertook extraordinary monetary policy measures to help stabilise financial markets, restore economic growth and fight the threat of deflation. These unconventional policy measures included liquidity provisions, the purchase of financial assets (quantitative easing, QE) and forward guidance (see Box 2, which quantifies Swiss Re’s financial repression index). Among other effects, this led to a massive increase in central banks’ balance sheets; both in absolute terms and as a percentage of GDP (see Figure 1). Source: Swiss Re, Bloomberg More than half a decade after the end of the recession, central bank policy rates in the US, UK, Eurozone and Japan remain at historic lows, and unconventional policy measures are still in place (Figure 2). Federal Reserve QE ended in October 2014; Fed remains “patient in beginning to normalise the stance of monetary policy” European Central Bank After cutting its key interest rates to the “zero-bound”, the ECB announced that it will implement a broad-based asset purchase programme with a size of EUR 60 billion per month Bank of England Completed three rounds of QE, total of GBP 375 billion in assets; set out ‘phase 2’ of forward guidance in February 2014 aimed at eliminating the spare capacity in the economy Bank of Japan Quantitative and qualitative easing policy, targeting an increase in the monetary base of JPY 80 trillion per year “as long as it is necessary” for achieving a 2% inflation rate But central bank policies have started to take diverging paths. While the Fed and the Bank of England (BoE) are preparing to start increasing interest rates at some point in 2015, the European Central Bank (ECB) and Bank of Japan (BoJ) maintain a commitment to extraordinary measures. This divergence is likely to become even more apparent in the future. Interest rate hiking cycles have historically been less coordinated than easing cycles; economic fundamentals and the reactions of individual central banks are what matter now. Figure 1: Balance sheets of G4 central banks, from 2000 onwards (USD trillion) 0 2 4 6 8 10 12 BoE BoJ Fed ECB 2012201020082006200420022000 Figure 2: Unconventional policies of G4 central banks
  • 9. Swiss Re Financial repression: The unintended consequences  7 US Eurozone UK Japan EMs Normalising monetary policy. Going back to interest rate policy From fragmenta­ tion to robust integration. A complex undertaking Policy normalisation to start gradually. UK economy outperforms the Eurozone From deflation to reflation. The jury is still out Addressing spillovers from G4 central bank policies. See market reaction in May 2013 as the Fed tapered Source: Swiss Re Figure 3: Transition from liquidity-driven to growth-driven markets 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 Index level Financial repression index January 2000 January 2002 January 2004 January 2006 January 2008 January 2010 January 2012 January 2014   Monetary      Regulatory      Others Box 2: Swiss Re financial repression index Financial repression reflects the ability of policymakers to direct funds to themselves that would otherwise go elsewhere. Swiss Re has developed its own financial repression index that is based on the following three broad components (see Appendix for methodology): a. Monetary: i) real yields, ii) difference of long-term government bond yields to their ‘fair value’, iii) central bank QE purchases and holdings, and iv) divergence of policy rate from Taylor rule b. Regulatory: i) regulatory risk and (ii) the consequences thereof, namely a) asset encumbrance and b) availability of high-quality assets c. Others: Banks’ domestic sovereign debt holdings and capital flow development The index suggests that financial repression is currently high on a historical basis, though down from its 2011–2012 peak. The major driver of change post-2007–2008 has been monetary policy (grey). Regulatory changes featured prominently post- 2011 (blue). Within the blue area, the contribution from the inflexibility of banks’ balance sheets (asset encumbrance) has declined from the peak in 2011–2012. Debt holdings and capital flows (light blue, i.e. “others”) have been a stronger driver more recently. Source: Swiss Re
  • 10. 8  Swiss Re Financial repression: The unintended consequences Financial repression has broken the credit intermediation channel. Long-term investors are crowded out of some markets, lowering their ability to channel funds to the real economy. Infrastructure investments would repair this damage and address weak economic growth.
  • 11. Swiss Re Financial repression: The unintended consequences  9
  • 12. 10  Swiss Re Financial repression: The unintended consequences Unintended consequences of financial repression Why do central banks engage in unorthodox monetary policies? Key objectives include bringing inflation back to target, stabilising financial markets and fostering economic growth. While the jury is still out on their success and ability to achieve those goals, one effect is clear: Low interest rates help governments to fund their debt. In other words, they are able to channel funds to themselves – referred to as financial repression. This type of policymaking comes at a cost. So far, central bankers have argued that the benefits of quantitative easing and other unorthodox measures outweigh the costs. However, exiting ultra-easy monetary policy will become harder with time and the unintended consequences will become more apparent. These include potential asset bubbles, a financial repression “tax”, increasing economic inequality, the potential of higher inflation and reputation damage for central banks. The debate among central bankers on the potential unintended consequences of the “Great Monetary Experiment” has already intensified somewhat, in particular related to the implications for economic inequality2. However, the focus on the topic remains rather tepid at best and more informed public policy discussions are necessary. Asset price bubbles Financial markets hit lows in 2009, but have since strongly recovered. The SP500 has advanced by roughly 200% since March 2009 when it hit its lowest point. At least part of this rally was liquidity-driven as a result of extraordinary central bank policy measures (see Figure 4). Source: Swiss Re, Bloomberg The low yield environment post-2008 has seen investors shift from investment grade into higher yielding assets and emerging market bonds, particularly over the period 2009–2012 (Figure 5). Figure 4: Fed balance sheet and SP500 400 600 800 1000 1200 1400 1600 1800 2000 2200 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 SP 500 index level Fed balance sheet (USD trn) -rhs (right-hand side) 0.5 1.0 1.5 2.0 2.5 3.0 3.5 4.0 4.5 5.0 2 E.g. see ECB Governing Council member Mersch, 17 October 2014, “Monetary policy and economic inequality“; Fed Chairwoman Yellen, 17 October 2014, “Perspectives on inequality and opportunity from the survey of consumer finances“
  • 13. Swiss Re Financial repression: The unintended consequences  11 Source: Swiss Re, EPFR Database There has been some convergence between the US and Europe in fixed income asset allocation since 2000, notably in the insurance sector (see Figure 6). European insurers’ fixed income allocation rose from around 40% in 2000 to almost 55% currently. At the same time, equity allocation has dropped significantly. It is currently at 25–30% as opposed to 32–38% in 20004. Pension funds increased their equity allocation in Europe and the US, with the majority of the increase being in the US. Source: Swiss Re, OECD Database. Note: Europe represents the average of the UK, Germany, France, Italy and Spain The significant price appreciation across asset classes post-2009 suggests the risk of a market-wide asset price bubble. Forward equity price to earnings (P/E) ratios have moved above their long-term average, while cyclically-adjusted Shiller P/E Figure 5: Strong fund inflows into DM and EM bond funds3 over 2009–2012 (% of assets under management) -10 0 10 20 30 40 50 60 EM Bond Funds Corporate HY Bond Funds International Bond Funds 201420132012201120102009 % Figure 6: Insurers’ and pension funds’ allocation to fixed income assets over time 20 30 40 50 60 70 US insurers European insurers European pension funds US pension funds 20132012201120102009200820072006200520042003200220012000 3 Equity fund flows have been less predictable over the years, but there were net inflows into EM and Japanese equity funds. Cumulatively since 2009, inflows into EM and Japanese equity funds totaled 40% and 30% of AuM respectively, vs. roughly zero into US and Western European equity funds 4 The equity allocation figures might also include other equity-linked investments apart from listed or private stocks, ie variable-yield securities and units in unit trusts. This is based on OECD data covering the broad insurance industry across countries
  • 14. 12  Swiss Re Financial repression: The unintended consequences Unintended consequences of financial repression ratios are back at pre-crisis levels. The same is true for investment grade corporate credit and securitised product spreads. Some asset class segments look particularly overvalued. These include collateralised loan obligations (CLOs), high-yield corporate credit and leveraged loans. Housing markets are vulnerable to easy money and asset bubbles. Markets in London, China and in some Scandinavian countries are most at risk of a significant correction. The longer the current monetary policy stance is maintained, the longer those risks will continue to build up. Clearly, financial market excess (FME) has been building up due to increased risk appetite and low market volatility. The Swiss Re FME index is now close to pre-crisis average levels (see Figure 7). The Fed has warned about these risks on a number of occasions, even though they have largely been engineered by the Fed itself. In a February 2013 speech, former Fed Governor Jeremy Stein highlighted the over­ heating in credit markets. In her semi-annual testimony, Fed Chairwoman Janet Yellen later identified small cap, biotech and social media stocks as being highly valued relative to the historical norm. Source: Swiss Re, Bloomberg, Morningstar, DB, MS Note: The index is based on a variety of measures that cover different aspects of potential market exuberance: (i) market risk sentiment: Swiss Re Market Risk Appetite Index; (ii) market activity: MA deal count; (iii) leverage: CCC issuance share of HY issuance and net debt/EBITDA for high-yield; (iv) fund flows: equity and high-yield mutual fund flows; (v) valuation: cyclically adjusted P/E ratio (SPX) and high-yield spreads to US Treasuries; and (vi) volatility: realised stock market volatility (SPX). The index is calculated as the average of the Z-scores for the nine factors, based on the five-year pre-crisis period from 2002 to 2007, and is then transformed to a 0–1 scale. The index frequency is weekly. Figure 7: US Financial Market Excess (FME) index 0.0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1.0 1.2 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 20132012 2014
  • 15. Swiss Re Financial repression: The unintended consequences  13 Impact on private households The prevailing low interest rate environment and the strong performance of financial assets due to loose monetary policy have a profound impact on savers and institutional investors’ portfolio returns. Some regard this as another example of financial repression. Reinhart and Sbrancia (2011) summarise it thus as: “unlike income, consumption, or sales taxes, the ‘repression’ tax rate […] may be a more politically palatable alternative to authorities.” Unconventional central bank policies not only affect the interest-bearing assets of households (accounting for roughly 30% of household wealth), but other investments such as equity (~40% of household wealth, including mutual funds) and real estate (25% of household wealth) – see Figure 8. Source: Swiss Re, US Federal Reserve Households are being ‘taxed’ as they do not earn interest on their deposits that they otherwise would. In case of negative real interest rates, they even experience a devaluation of their savings in real terms. Had the Fed followed a simple Taylor rule5, the policy target rate would have been roughly 1.7 percentage points higher on average in the period 2008–2013. Assuming the lower rate had been passed on to depositors, the foregone annual interest earnings from savings accounts amount to USD 14 000 per adult for the top 1% wealthiest; and USD 160 for the bottom 90%. For pension and life insurance assets, with 10-year US bond yields having traded roughly 1.2 percentage points below their ‘fair value’6 on average since 2008, foregone interest for the top 1% amounts to roughly USD 9 000 per adult. Clearly, low interest rates also reduce debt costs; with lower mortgage rates providing the bulk of the relief7. On a net basis, the foregone interest earnings amount to roughly 0.3% of total financial assets for both the top 1% and top 10% wealthiest adults (see Figure 9). For the remaining, the significant advantage of lower debt costs (mainly mortgages) translates into a ‘subsidy’ of 0.3% of financial assets. Since the financial crisis, the total cumulative Figure 8: US household wealth asset allocation 0% 10% 20% 30% 40% 50% 60% 70% 80% 90% 100% Other Fixed income Equity Currency and deposits Mutual funds Life insurance and pension Real Estate 2013201220112010200920082007 USD trn 77 66 68 72 73 79 88 5 Taylor-rule rate = Neutral real policy rate + core CPI + 0.5*(Inflation target – core CPI) + 0.5* (NAIRU – unemployment rate) 6 “Fair value“ computed as potential GDP growth rate + inflation target of 2%. Note: this analysis ignores any realised gains or losses on the fixed income holdings, taking a pure running investment income view 7 As for pension and life insurance assets, the assumption is that debt costs have been 1.2% lower than “fair value“, on average
  • 16. 14  Swiss Re Financial repression: The unintended consequences net “tax” on all US households amounts to roughly USD 470 billion. This represents an average “tax” of 0.2% per annum on total financial wealth (including interest-bearing assets and equities), or 0.4% of total interest-bearing assets. Source: Swiss Re, Credit Suisse Global Wealth Databook, 2013, Wolff, 2012, “The Asset Price Meltdown and the Wealth of the Middle Class“ Meanwhile, the wealthier savers have benefited more from the equity rally with the top 1% having 50% of their financial assets invested in equities (while the bottom 90% only allocates 9% on average). Assuming that, on average, US savers have profited from a 100% appreciation of their equity portfolio during the 2009–2013 period (and ignoring the losses from pre-crisis legacy holdings), this results in a gain of USD 3.7 million for the top 1% of households and USD 7 300 for the bottom 90%. As a percentage of total financial wealth, the top 1% has thus recorded a 50% gain while the bottom 90% only registered a 12% profit (see Figure 10). This suggests that monetary policy and central bank asset purchases have aggravated economic inequality via equity price inflation. Overall, the actual value of equity holdings in US household portfolios has risen by roughly USD 9 trillion since 20088. * Assuming US savers have profited from a 100% appreciation; ignoring legacy holdings. Note: Figures rounded Source: Swiss Re, Credit Suisse Global Wealth Databook, 2013, Wolff, 2012, “The Asset Price Meltdown and the Wealth of the Middle Class“ Figure 9: Annual impact on US savers’ interest earnings/costs from (too) low interest rates Three categories: The wealthiest 1%, the wealthiest 10% and the remaining 90%, from 2008–2013, per adult –5 0 5 10 15 Debt costs Pension and life insurance Deposits Bottom 90%Top 10%Top 1% 13.9 9.1 3.5 –1.9 –4.1 0.2 0.2 –0.6 3.0 USD, in thousand % of total financial wealth –0.4 –0.3 –0.2 –0.1 0.0 0.1 0.2 0.3 0.4 Net “tax” as % of total financial wealth (rhs) Figure 10: Average gains from the 2009–2013 equity rally in US household portfolios (per adult)* 0 500000 1000000 1500000 2000000 2500000 3000000 3500000 4000000 Gain per adult bottom 90%top 10%top 1% 3.7mn USD % of total financial wealth 690tsd 7tsd 0% 10% 20% 30% 40% 50% 60% 70% 80% Gain as % of total financial wealth (rhs) Unintended consequences of financial repression 8 US Federal Reserve data
  • 17. Swiss Re Financial repression: The unintended consequences  15 Finally, low interest rates may also have impacted house prices through lower mortgage costs, thus increasing refinancing activity and housing demand. Historically, a decline in the real long-term interest rate by 100 basis points was found to have increased house prices by up to 7%9. A simple regression of the log house price (FHFA US house price index) on the real 10-year US interest rate10 confirms these findings (impact is found to be around 5%). This translates into an increase in household wealth of roughly USD 1 trillion based on the assumption that long-term real interest rates have been roughly 1.2 percentage points below their ‘fair value’, on average, since 2008. As a percentage of total financial wealth, the bottom 90% wealth class has profited most, even though from an absolute perspective the gain for the top 10% richest is still multiple times higher. In conclusion, the impact of financial repression on US household wealth has been lower net interest income, which might be understood as a “tax” on savers. It has been counterbalanced by the increase in wealth due to the appreciation in the value of equity and real estate holdings (see Figure 11). Estimated impact Wealth distribution effect The financial repression “tax” USD –470 billion Top 10% are taxed, while bottom 90% are subsidised Change in household wealth House price increase*: USD +1 trillion From an absolute perspective, equity and house price gains have mostly benefited the richer part of society. As a % of financial wealth, housing gains have helped the poorer part of society Equity gains**: USD +9 trillion * Assuming +5% is attributable to central bank policy. The wealth impact from rising home values was likely offset by homeowner deleveraging ** Reflecting the value change of US households equity positions in their portfolios. Arguably, this assumption is rather optimistic as the pure stock price appreciation attributable to financial repression was likely much smaller Whether the increase in wealth has led to the so-called “wealth effect” (ie impact on actual consumption) is questionable. Unlike interest income on deposits, equity and real estate value appreciation are not realisable cash gains immediately available for consumption. Also, property prices have not yet fully recovered their loss from the 2008–2009 period. Households are thus still worse off compared to pre-crisis. Moreover, outstanding mortgage debt has continued to decline even after the trough in home prices11. This indicates that the gain in households’ real estate portfolio values was at least partially offset by reducing the value of mortgage debt. Overall, there is no clear evidence of equity-related gains having translated into additional consumption and thus no real economic growth (see Figure 12, only a very weak relationship). A similar picture holds for the “wealth effect” related to housing. As a result, the increase in financial and housing wealth has – at best – only marginally benefited the real economy. Indeed, households’ foregone interest income (the “tax”) was certainly not positive for spending. Meanwhile, the equity and property value gains had a significant impact on wealth inequality, as the richest households have profited significantly in absolute terms. The “wealth effect” is also questionable given population aging and the life-cycle hypothesis12. At lower interest rates, more aggregate savings are required for an aging population to maintain their consumption level post-retirement (see Box 3). Figure 11: Impact of financial repression – the “tax” and household wealth 9 Glaeser  Gottlieb, 2010, “Can cheap credit explain the housing boom“ 10 As suggested by Glaeser  Gottlieb, 2010 11 Since mid-2011, US loan-to-value ratios have dropped from almost 55% to 42% with outstanding mortgage debt having declined by 5% (Source: Bloomberg) 12 An economic theory that relates to individuals‘ consumption habits over the course of a lifetime.
  • 18. 16  Swiss Re Financial repression: The unintended consequences Source: Hoisington Quarterly Review and Outlook, Q1 2014 Figure 12: Real consumption vs. SP500 (1930–2013) Real per capita PCE, % change Real SP 500, % change R2 = 0.27 15 10 5 0 –5 –10 –15 –50 –40 –30 –20 –10 0 5040302010 Elderly-dependency ratios (%) Box 3: Demographic trends, low interest rates and the “wealth effect” Population aging is likely to become a bigger focus for financial market developments in the coming years, especially as the dependency ratios in many major economies are to rise significantly. The available labour force will decrease, and the elderly will increasingly make up a larger propor­ tion of the population. This will bring further social and economic challenges. As seen in the Figure below, Japan, Spain and Germany are at the higher end of the spectrum with dependency ratios of at least 60% expected by 2050. Meanwhile, the US population is expected to age much slower. With most governments already facing unsustainable debt, rising age-related spending only aggravates the problem. Moreover, there is a risk that the finan­ cing need will further create incentives for governments to implement even more expansionary policies. Putting this aside, several question marks emerge related to current financial repression policies: According to the life-cycle hypothesis of con­ sumption and saving, during retire­ment an aging population reduces its savings and disinvests its asset holdings in order to support consumption. This means that the “wealth effect”, as reflected by policies to support the equity market for fuelling consumption growth, will be even less effective. At lower interest rates, more needs to be saved on aggregate for an aging population in order to maintain the consumption level post-retirement when the accumulated savings are spent. 0 10 20 30 40 50 60 70 80 2050 2030 2015 2010 India Brazil China US Australia Canada Switzerland Spain UK France Italy Germany Japan Unintended consequences of financial repression Source: UN Database
  • 19. Swiss Re Financial repression: The unintended consequences  17 Impact on institutional investors Institutional investors such as re/insurers and pension funds hold a significant part of their assets in fixed income securities given their business need to match long- term liabilities. As such, their investment income has been significantly impacted by prevailing low interest rates. Life insurers in particular struggle to meet their guaranteed rates. Although the guaranteed life insurance credit rate has declined in recent years, it is still significantly above the respective 10-year government bond yield (around 2.5% vs ~1% typical European 10-year bond yield13). Re/insurers’ running yields14 have declined over recent years, following a similar path as 30 year US Treasury yields (see Figure 13). Had US Treasuries (or German Bunds) been trading closer to their ‘fair value’ (implied by potential GDP growth and an inflation target of 2%), running yields would have been roughly 0.5–1 percentage points higher on average for the 2008–2013 period15. Given re/insurers’ allocation to fixed income assets of 50–60%16, this would have translated into roughly USD 20–40 billion additional income overall for both US and European insurers. A sensitivity analysis of insurers’ running investment income to additional running yield is shown in Figure 14. For pension funds, the impact of 1 percentage point of additional running yield would be similar – a total additional income of USD 40–50 billion per annum. The pension industry’s asset base is somewhat larger, but the average allocation to fixed income is smaller than in the insurance sector. Source: Swiss Re, Bloomberg, OECD Database, Insurance Europe, 2014, “European Insurance in Figures“ Figure 13: US insurers’ running yields vs. 30 year Treasuries 2% 3% 4% 5% 6% 7% 30yr UST yield (%) US PC running yield US LH running yield Q4/01 Q4/03 Q4/05 Q4/07 Q4/09 Q4/11 Q4/13 Figure 14: Insurers‘ investment income as a function of additional running yield 0 10 20 30 40 50 60 70 80 European insurers US insurers 0.10.30.50.70.91.11.31.5 USD bn Additional running yield 13 EIOPA Financial Stability Report, May 2014 14 Annualised investment return based on average invested assets. Excludes realised gains/losses 15 Computed as actual 30Y government bond yield – [“fair value“ (which is assumed to hold for 10Y government bonds) + historical 30Y–10Y term premium of ~50bps] 16 Insurance Europe, 2014, “European Insurance in Figures“ and OECD Database. Note that the fixed income allocation might be understated due to OECD classification of “miscellaneous assets“, mutual funds, unit trusts, money market fund shares etc.
  • 20. 18  Swiss Re Financial repression: The unintended consequences Though this analysis ignores any realised gains or losses from the fixed income assets, Box 4 shows the tremendous impact that financial repression can have on long-term investors. “Tax” on pension funds and insurers Average of the US, UK and Eurozone Box 4: The “opaque tax” on long-term investors Foregone interest income represents an “opaque tax” on insurance companies and pension funds – on average currently estimated at 0.4– 0.8% p.a. of their total financial assets for the US and Europe (see Figure below). Assuming a 4–8 times asset leverage embedded in insurers’ balance sheets, this would translate into a drag on RoE of ~4% on average. Besides the impact on long-term investors’ portfolio income, the consequences for financial market intermediation are not negligible either: Crowding out investors due to artificially low yields will also reduce the diversification of funding sources to the real economy, thus representing a risk for financial stability and economic growth at large. -1.5 -1.0 -0.5 0.0 0.5 1.0 1.5 Penison funds’ tax Insurers’ tax Jan 1997 Jan 2001 Jan 2005 Jan 2009 Jan 2013 “Financial Repression” Zone Note: A positive number indicates a “tax” on the investor, while a negative number can be considered a “subsidy” % of Total Financial Assets Unintended consequences of financial repression Source: Swiss Re
  • 21. Swiss Re Financial repression: The unintended consequences  19 Inflation and credibility Major central banks face a trade-off between supporting economic recovery and contributing to the further potential build-up of financial and economic imbalances, in particular the risk of long-term inflation. While inflation is currently low, this could change over the medium- to long-term given extraordinarily accommodative central bank policies and the gradual reduction of economic overcapacity. Longer-term inflation risks are to the upside given the current Fed focus on growth, which has contributed to the massive increase in central bank balance sheets (see Figure 15) and the high sovereign debt levels across major economies. The danger of a hyper inflationary scenario, however, remains distant. Source: Swiss Re, Bloomberg. Note: Central banks include BoE, BoJ, ECB, Fed and SNB. World GDP is based on PPP in current USD trillion Post-financial crisis, there is a broad consensus that central banks should increase their monitoring of financial stability risks in the context of overall macro stability. This switch in focus would raise the potential politicisation of central banks. An increase in supervisory powers must be balanced with maintaining central bank independence. Fed Chairwoman Janet Yellen has repeatedly stated that she does “not presently see a need for monetary policy to deviate from a primary focus on attaining price stability and maximum employment, in order to address financial stability concerns.” Instead, she believes that “a macro prudential approach to supervision and regulation needs to play the primary role.”17 Figure 15: Sum of major central bank balance sheets, in USD and as % of world GDP 0 2 4 6 8 10 12 2013201120092007200520032001 USD trn 0% 2% 4% 6% 8% 10% 12% in USD trn as a % of GDP (rhs) 17 Fed chairwoman Yellen‘s central banking lecture at the IMF, 2 July 2014
  • 22. 20  Swiss Re Financial repression: The unintended consequences Central banks face a trade- off between supporting economic recovery and contributing to the further potential build-up of financial and economic imbalances.
  • 23. Swiss Re Financial repression: The unintended consequences  21
  • 24. 22  Swiss Re Financial repression: The unintended consequences While some economies are recovering, notably the UK and the US, growth is more fragile in Japan and in the Eurozone. But even in countries experiencing better growth, central banks have yet to gain sufficient confidence in the strength of their economies to start exiting the extraordinary monetary conditions enacted post- 2008. At some point central banks will have to exit unconventional monetary policies and raise rates again. So, what will happen if they change their accommodative approach? Most significant for the global economy will be the tightening of US monetary policy. This will imply long- and short-term challenges. In the short-term, they will include: (i) maintaining credible and consistent communication as economic data further improves; (ii) preventing unnecessary and excessive market volatility amid the even­ tual shift to a more hawkish stance; and (iii) technical implementation of the exit, with the new fixed-rate reverse repo facility likely to play an important role in the Fed’s exit toolkit. Long term, the fundamental question arises of whether too much is being asked of central banks. As already stated by Paul Volcker18, “the Federal Reserve – any central bank – should not be asked to do too much, to undertake responsibilities that it cannot reasonably meet with the appropriately limited powers provided.” Amid the general recognition that more attention must be paid to financial stability risks in the future, the key questions are: How can monetary and regulatory policies be optimally coordinated to achieve greater financial stability? And, what is the best institutional setup in order to safeguard central bank independence? Capital market outlook The Fed’s hiking cycle is likely to be closely watched, as it impacts both developed and emerging market economies. The ECB and BoJ are expected to remain in accommodative mode for some time yet. With growth below the long-term trend and inflation tame, the Fed’s rate hikes are likely to be gradual. A repeat of the 1994 bond market collapse, when the Fed’s policy rate increased by 300 basis points in a single year, seems unlikely. The hiking cycles in 1990–2000 and 2004–2006 are better comparisons. In 1999–2000, the Fed raised rates by 1.5 percentage points. The Barclays Aggregate U.S. Bond Index19 lost just 0.8% in 1999 before rebounding 11.6% in 2000. In 2004–2006, the Fed raised rates 17 times, from 1.0% to 5.25%. During those three years, the Barclays index delivered positive returns. An important difference, however, is that yields were higher in the two previous episodes noted than they are today (though investment grade spreads20 were fairly similar to today), offering more income to offset potential price declines. The equity market’s initial reaction in all three instances was a sell-off, with the SP 500 Index ending down by an average of 3.2% after a one-month period. The average price rise over six-month periods after the start of each rate-hiking cycle was still positive at 2.6%. After 12 months, the average return was 6.2%, 200 basis points below the long-term average annual price change21 (Figure 16). Exiting monetary policy 18 Remarks by Paul A. Volcker, May 29, 2013, “Central banking at a crossroad“ 19 Formerly the Lehman Aggregate index. The index includes sovereign, quasi-sovereign and corporate bonds 20 For US investment grade, having lost 2% in 1999, total return was 9.1% in 2000. Over 2004–2006, the index returned 5.4%, 1.7% and 4.3% respectively 21 AAII Journal, “Don‘t Fight the Fed: Interest Rates and their Impact on the Stock Market“, Sam Stovall, May 2009
  • 25. Swiss Re Financial repression: The unintended consequences  23 In other words, rate increases and the prospect of higher interest rates have constrained equity market rallies. Much will depend on the extent to which the US economy can recover in the absence of stimulus and how much of the equity rally to date has been driven by central bank liquidity. What is more certain is that market volatility is likely to pick up, and central bank policy errors have the potential to be more detrimental. There is a good case for seeing a different equity reaction to the eventual tightening of rates in the current cycle. 0 4 8 12 16 12 Months 6 Months After Rate CutsAll YearsAfter Rate Hikes Source: SP equity research, quoted in AAII Journal, “Don’t Fight the Fed: Interest Rates and their Impact on the Stock Market“, Sam Stovall, May 2009 Sovereign vulnerability Higher US sovereign bond yields will lead to increased financing costs and tighter financial conditions for many emerging market countries. Those needing to fund large current account deficits, such as Turkey and South Africa, were shown to be vulnerable to capital flows in May/June 2013. However, if US sovereign bond yields increase gradually, accompanied by stronger US growth, the shock element for emerging markets is expected to be less severe. Markets are also more likely to differentiate between the stronger and weaker emerging market economies. A number of these countries took steps to address their vulnerabilities after the emerging market volatility of 2013. Among the ‘fragile five’ emerging markets, India has been most successful in reducing its current account deficit (Figure 17). The new government is expected to take further steps to reduce the fiscal deficit and inflation. Brazil, Turkey and South Africa are struggling to address their current account gap, although Brazil’s foreign exchange reserves are significantly higher than those of Turkey and South Africa. There are several other Latin American countries with moderately high current account deficits, such as Peru and Chile, but their deficits are better covered by long-term foreign direct investment (FDI) flows, and are less vulnerable to capital flight. Figure 16: SP 500 % changes after interest rate hikes and cuts 1946–2008
  • 26. 24  Swiss Re Financial repression: The unintended consequences Exiting monetary policy Source: Swiss Re, Bloomberg As the major central banks exit the ultra-accommodative policy environment, highly indebted developed countries will become more exposed to rising financing costs. Since the crisis, sovereign debt levels in Europe have increased significantly (Figure 18). In Spain and Ireland, sovereign debt as a percentage of GDP more than doubled between 2007 and 2013. If growth does not pick up sufficiently to offset the rise in financing costs, the debt sustainability of some of these countries will become more challenging. Source: Swiss Re, IMF WEO Database China’s ‘exit’ from financial repression is expected to take the form of interest rate and capital market liberalisation. This will have major repercussions for both developed and emerging markets. Interest rate liberalisation should gradually lift rates in China. Together with other reforms, China’s reliance on growth from investment will likely slow over time. This will lead to lower commodity prices, negatively impacting commodity exporters such as Australia, Chile, Peru and Brazil. Furthermore, Asian economies that have strong trade links with mainland China, including Hong Kong, South Korea, Taiwan and Singapore, are likely to face a slowdown in export growth. Figure 17: Current account deficits among the ‘fragile five’ countries % GDP –9 –8 –7 –6 –5 –4 –3 –2 –1 0 Turkey South Africa India Brazil Indonesia Sep 14Jun 14Mar 14Dec 13Sep 13Jun 13Mar 13Dec 12Sep 12Jun 12 Figure 18: Sovereign debt (gross) as a % of GDP 0 50 100 150 200 250 2013 2007 JapanIrelandPortugalFranceItalySpainGermanyUKUS
  • 27. Swiss Re Financial repression: The unintended consequences  25 While the pace of China’s capital market liberalisation is uncertain, increases in gross capital flows will most likely be substantial. Capital account liberalisation has historically often been followed by an exchange rate or banking crisis22. This would have a significant impact on global financial market stability as China becomes more integrated with global markets. For example, Figure 19 shows that UK banks’ claims on China increased tenfold between 2005 and 2013; and are set to rise more with further liberalisation. Loan exposures to mainland Chinese corporates by Hong Kong, Singaporean and Taiwanese banks doubled over recent years, now standing at 27%, 9% and 6% of total banking assets23 respectively. Source: Swiss Re, BIS Database Figure 19: Foreign bank claims on China (USD million), with the UK leading the pack 0 200 400 600 800 1000 Others Taiwanese Banks Japanese Banks Australian Banks US Banks European Banks - Others European Banks - German European Banks - French European Banks - UK Dec13 Dec12 Dec11 Dec10 Dec09 Dec08 Dec07 Dec06 Dec05 22 Kaminsky and Schmukler, IMF Working Paper 2003, “Short-Run Pain, Long-Run Gain: The Effect of Financial Liberalization“, Magud, Reinhart and Vesperoni, IMF Working Paper 2012, “Capital Inflows, Exchange Rate Flexibility, and Credit Booms“ 23 UBS, February 2014, “HK/Singapore’s growing financial links to China“, BIS Database
  • 28. 26  Swiss Re Financial repression: The unintended consequences Infrastructure investments and growth Long-term investors are part of the intermediation channel that helps move saving funds to the real economy. Keeping interest rates artificially low through public intervention can have significant consequences on long-term investors, including crowding out viable private markets. A healthy financial intermediation channel is needed to sustain financial market stability and support economic growth. Investments in infrastructure are not only growth-enhancing strategies, they also offer attractive and suitable investment opportunities for long-term investors. With the global economic recovery being weak by historical standards and output in several countries lower than pre-crisis levels, the provision of long-term funds to the economy is urgently needed. Moreover, institutional investors such as re/insurers and pension funds require such investments to match their long-term liabilities, as well as to improve their portfolio returns in the current low-yield environment (see also joint Swiss Re/IIF publications24). Assessing the impact of infrastructure investment on economic growth, two primary channels can be identified. First, infrastructure capital increases production capacity. Second, it may also raise productivity. In theory, both effects will lead to higher GDP, but the magnitude of the potential increase has been debated for a long time. Academic studies estimate that 10% more infrastructure capital can boost the long- term GDP growth rate by 0.9 percentage points25. The IMF26 has also found that in a low economic growth environment, USD 1 of infrastructure spending results in almost USD 3 of additional economic output. Infrastructure investments also lower the production costs of manufacturing firms, in turn raising their productivity27. A recent SP study28 estimated that a USD 1.3 billion infrastructure investment would likely add 29 000 jobs to the construction sector and USD 2 billion to US real economic growth. Indeed, the importance of infrastructure investment for economic growth has been recognised globally, with the topic ranking high on the G20 agenda under the Australian presidency. Some USD 50–70 trillion will be needed to finance infrastructure globally through 2030. Thereby, we estimate that the current spending of roughly USD 2.6 trillion annually will have to increase to around USD 4 trillion by 2030. This emerging financing gap, estimated at roughly USD 1 trillion annually (also highlighted by the WEF29), will have to be met in order to support economic growth. Though commercial banks will remain key players, institutional investors such as re/insurers and pension funds have a potentially much larger role to play. Infrastructure investments provide a good balance given the steady cash flows and potential to match investors’ long-term liabilities. However, several impediments remain to unlocking the large long-term institutional investor asset base of roughly USD 75 trillion globally. Besides regulatory uncertainty, there is a lack of an investable and transparent asset class. Indeed, the current infrastructure allocation of pension funds and re/insurers remains below the average target allocation (3% vs 5%, and 2% vs 3%, respectively), as indicated in Figure 20. 24 “Strengthening the Role of Long-term Investors“, 2013; “Infrastructure Investing. It Matters“, 2014 25 Bom and Ligthart, CESifo working paper, January 2008 26 IMF World Economic Outlook, October 2014 27 The American Economic Review, Morrison  Schwartz, December 1996, “State Infrastructure and Productive Performance“ 28 SP, May 2014, “US infrastructure investment: A chance to reap more than we sow“ 29 WEF, 2014, “Infrastructure Investment Policy Blueprint“
  • 29. Swiss Re Financial repression: The unintended consequences  27 Source: Investing in infrastructure: “Are insurers ready to fill the funding gap?” SP, 2014. Note: Superannuation funds are government supported and encouraged investment funds. Here, AustralianSuper, which is Australia‘s largest superannuation/pension fund with AUD 75 billion AuM, is considered. One of the challenges in bringing greater finance into infrastructure investments is, as mentioned, the lack of a tradable asset class; this hinders depth and liquidity within a market for infrastructure investment. Consequently, private capital market solutions are urgently needed. A proposal for what such a solution could look like is described in Box 5. Figure 20: Breakdown of average current/target allocation to infrastructure 9 8 7 6 5 4 3 2 1 0 Insurance company Asset manager Familyoffice Foundation Endowment plan Private-sector pensionfund Publicpension fund Sovereign wealthfund Superannuation scheme % Average current allocation to infrastructure Average target allocation to infrastructure
  • 30. 28  Swiss Re Financial repression: The unintended consequences Infrastructure investments and growth Box 5: Swiss Re proposal to create a tradable long-term global investment instrument A tradable global infrastructure asset class is needed to attract long-term investors. Despite being well positioned to provide long-term capital, institutional investors require the ability to make adjustments to their portfolios as needed – including to their infrastruc­ ture debt holdings where, for instance, sudden changes in the regulatory landscape can signifi­cantly change the risk characteristics of their investments. As such, a tradable asset class would unlock the long-term investor asset base, and simultaneously also serve as a disciplining instrument for govern­ ments when considering policy or regulatory changes. As local infra­ structure funding needs to compete with the more established markets, such an asset class should be created on a global level. In Europe, the current EU/EIB project bond initiative would be a good starting point for a global model. The EU model as well as other initiatives (such as the Build America Infrastructure Initiative and the World Bank Global Infrastructure Facility) could benefit from the following structural elements: i) standardised reporting and debt documentation terms; ii) pooling of projects; and iii) possible additional capacity from re/insurance risk coverage In order to deal with the heterogeneity of infrastructure projects, pools with projects from similar industries could be created, thus providing significant diversification benefits to investors. Consequently, there is a case for private market participants to work together with the public sector in creating a “Global Project Bond Market” and infrastructure asset class (see graph above). * Possibly lower central bank repo haircuts and lower regulatory capital charges due to the new features ** Pre-conditions could include: no open cession structure, alignment with risk appetite and interests Central Banks Long-term investors Standardised Pan-regional Projects Bonds (“Covered bond-like” structure) In blue: additional elements to EU/EIB Project Bond Initiatives Insurance InvestCollateral* Project Company 1 Project Company 2 Project Company 3 Infrastructure debt Standardised Project Pool with public-private partnership (PPP)- character. The pools can either be a mix of both construction and operational phase projects, or otherwise separated. Truststructure Multilateral development banks/ National development banks (Un-)funded credit enhancement of subordinated debt Re/insurer Provide risk coverage subject to pre- conditions**
  • 31. Swiss Re Financial repression: The unintended consequences  29 Concluding remarks 30 See IMF World Economic Outlook, October 2014. Looking ahead, financial repression is likely to remain a key tool for policymakers given the moderate global growth outlook and high public debt overhang. But, as outlined in this paper, financial repression comes with significant costs. Whether the costs outweigh the benefits largely depends on the ability of governments to take advantage of the low interest rate environment by implementing the right structural reforms. So far, their record for doing so has not been comforting, as also noted by the IMF30. Additional research on financial repression could be linked to the impact of an aging society on the broader economic and financial market environment and hence the optimal policy mix. Finally, a largely unexplored area is the consequence – especially longer-term – of public authorities acting as dominant players in their own bond markets. How does this affect private capital markets, and how severe are the distortions in price formation, investment decisions, allocation to productive areas and capital flows more generally? Swiss Re’s current work on this topic is intended to contribute to the debate on the benefits-costs analysis and derive important implications for sustainable policymaking that will help build stable global capital markets. We should not wait for tomorrow to see the effect of the policy actions taken to date. Instead, we should put in place the elements for more stable markets today.
  • 32. 30  Swiss Re Financial repression: The unintended consequences
  • 33. Swiss Re Financial repression: The unintended consequences  31 Unintended consequences of financial repression include potential asset bubbles, a financial repression “tax”, increasing economic inequality, the potential of higher inflation, and reputation damage for central banks. So how long will it remain a key instrument in govern­ ments’ toolkits?
  • 34. 32  Swiss Re Financial repression: The unintended consequences Appendix Swiss Re Financial Repression Index – methodology Notes ̤̤ Both the monetary and regulatory components are assigned the same index weight (ie both 43%), and the “others” component (both regulatory and monetary elements) has an index weight of 14%. ̤̤ Real yields are computed for the 5Y bucket of the yield curve ̤̤ Fair values” are computed as potential GDP growth + inflation target of 2%. This is compared to the 10Y government bond yield ̤̤ Taylor-rule rate = Neutral real policy rate + core CPI + 0.5*(Inflation target – core CPI) + 0.5*(NAIRU – unemployment rate) ̤̤ Regulatory risk is measured using the Swiss Re Asset Management regulatory risk index, which is based on i) story count of regulatory risk in Bloomberg, and ii) the degree of bank equity returns not being explained by senior bank bond spreads (the residuals in the respective regression) ̤̤ Asset encumbrance is measured as follows: (ECB repos + ECB lending + Covered bonds outstanding)/total European banking sector assets. Currently, asset encumbrance across Europe is around 5% based on this methodology (which has also been used in the October 2013 IMF GFSR). Asset encumbrance is the “collateral damage” of financial repression, with regulatory reforms “forcing” institutions to pledge more assets, making the overall balance sheet less flexible ̤̤ Availability of high-quality assets is measured as the difference between repo rate and OIS rate. An increase in this spread indicates a scarcity in high-quality collateral (see BIS, 2013, “Asset encumbrance, financial reform and the demand for collateral assets”) ̤̤ Domestic debt holdings and capital flow consist of three variables: i) Sovereign bonds held by domestic banks (the “home bias”), ii) cross- border bank claims, iii) marketable sovereign debt (not held by central banks) ̤̤ Data frequency: In general, most data used for the index is available either on a monthly or more frequent basis. The exception is the ‘availability of high-quality liquid assets’ and the ‘other component’, where some data is only available on an annual basis ̤̤ Regional reach: Most components represent an average for the EU and the US. Asset encumbrance and high-quality liquid assets have a European focus only ̤̤ Data sources are Bloomberg, ECB, OECD, Bruegel and BIS Current level –1 year –5 years Overall index (sum of component contributors) 4.2 4.1 2.5 1. Real govt. bond yields 0.10 0.10 0.00 2. Difference actual yields vs. “fair value“ 0.65 0.45 0.10 3. Central bank asset purchases 0.35 0.40 0.05 4. Difference policy rate vs. “Taylor rule“ 0.75 0.60 0.20 5. Regulatory risk 0.90 0.90 0.50 6. Asset encumbrance 0.20 0.50 0.40 7. Availability of high-quality liquid assets 0.45 0.35 0.75 8. Domestic debts holdings and capital flows 0.75 0.75 0.55 Monetary components Regulatory components “Others“ Source: Swiss Re
  • 35. © 2015 Swiss Re. All rights reserved. Title: Financial repression: The unintended consequences Authors: Jérôme Haegeli Chuan Lim Tauno Loertscher Laurent Degoumois Steven Biekens Editing and realisation: Katharina Fehr Cushla Sherlock Managing editor: Urs Leimbacher Graphic design and production: Corporate Real Estate  Logistics/ Media Production, Zurich Printing: Corporate Real Estate  Logistics/ Media Production, Zurich Disclaimer: The content of this brochure is subject to copyright with all rights reserved. The information may be used for private or internal purposes, provided that any copyright or other proprietary notices are not removed. Electronic reuse of the content of this brochure is prohibited. Reproduction in whole or in part or use for any public purpose is only permitted with the prior written approval of Swiss Re, and if the source reference is indicated. Courtesy copies are appreciated. Swiss Re gives no advice and makes no investment recommendation to buy, sell or otherwise deal in securities or investments whatsoever. This document does not constitute an invitation to effect any transaction in securities or make investments. Although all the information used was taken from reliable sources, Swiss Re does not accept any res- ponsibility for the accuracy or comprehensiveness of the details given. All liability for the accuracy and completeness thereof or for any damage resulting from the use of the information contained in this brochure is expressly excluded. Under no circum- stances shall Swiss Re or its Group companies be liable for any financial and/or consequential loss relating to this brochure. Order no: 1506050_15_en 02/15, 1 000 en
  • 36. Swiss Reinsurance Company Ltd Mythenquai 50/60 P.O. Box 8022 Zurich Switzerland Telephone +41 43 285 2121 Fax +41 43 285 2999 www.swissre.com