SlideShare a Scribd company logo
1 of 160
Download to read offline
Ordeals and Redistribution
Piotr Dworczak*
(Northwestern University & GRAPE)
October 23, 2023
Based on research with Frank Yang and Mohammad Akbarpour
Normative Economics & Economic Policy webinar
*Co-funded by the European Union (ERC, IMD-101040122). Views and opinions expressed are those of the authors
only and do not necessarily reflect those of the European Union or the European Research Council.
Inequality-aware Market Design
 Inequality-aware Market Design (IMD): How to design
individual markets in the presence of inequality?
Inequality-aware Market Design
 Inequality-aware Market Design (IMD): How to design
individual markets in the presence of inequality?
 “Redistribution through markets” is very common:
Inequality-aware Market Design
 Inequality-aware Market Design (IMD): How to design
individual markets in the presence of inequality?
 “Redistribution through markets” is very common:
 rent control, public housing, food stamps, free road access, Covid-19
vaccines, legal services, in-kind provision of food items, controlling the
prices of energy, ...
Inequality-aware Market Design
 Inequality-aware Market Design (IMD): How to design
individual markets in the presence of inequality?
 “Redistribution through markets” is very common:
 rent control, public housing, food stamps, free road access, Covid-19
vaccines, legal services, in-kind provision of food items, controlling the
prices of energy, ...
 Given some redistributive preferences (welfare weights), what
is the best way to structure such policies under imperfect
information of the planner?
Inequality-aware Market Design
 Inequality-aware Market Design (IMD): How to design
individual markets in the presence of inequality?
 “Redistribution through markets” is very common:
 rent control, public housing, food stamps, free road access, Covid-19
vaccines, legal services, in-kind provision of food items, controlling the
prices of energy, ...
 Given some redistributive preferences (welfare weights), what
is the best way to structure such policies under imperfect
information of the planner?
 D r
⃝
Kominers r
⃝
Akbarpour (2021), A r
⃝
D r
⃝
K (2023), A r
⃝
Budish r
⃝
D
r
⃝
K (2023), Tokarski r
⃝
K r
⃝
A r
⃝
D (2023)
Inequality-aware Market Design
 Inequality-aware Market Design (IMD): How to design
individual markets in the presence of inequality?
 “Redistribution through markets” is very common:
 rent control, public housing, food stamps, free road access, Covid-19
vaccines, legal services, in-kind provision of food items, controlling the
prices of energy, ...
 Given some redistributive preferences (welfare weights), what
is the best way to structure such policies under imperfect
information of the planner?
 D r
⃝
Kominers r
⃝
Akbarpour (2021), A r
⃝
D r
⃝
K (2023), A r
⃝
Budish r
⃝
D
r
⃝
K (2023), Tokarski r
⃝
K r
⃝
A r
⃝
D (2023)
 Ongoing effort: Interaction of IMD with optimal taxation
Inequality-aware Market Design
 Inequality-aware Market Design (IMD): How to design
individual markets in the presence of inequality?
 “Redistribution through markets” is very common:
 rent control, public housing, food stamps, free road access, Covid-19
vaccines, legal services, in-kind provision of food items, controlling the
prices of energy, ...
 Given some redistributive preferences (welfare weights), what
is the best way to structure such policies under imperfect
information of the planner?
 D r
⃝
Kominers r
⃝
Akbarpour (2021), A r
⃝
D r
⃝
K (2023), A r
⃝
Budish r
⃝
D
r
⃝
K (2023), Tokarski r
⃝
K r
⃝
A r
⃝
D (2023)
 Ongoing effort: Interaction of IMD with optimal taxation
 Doligalski, D, Krysta, and Tokarski (2023)
Ordeals and Redistribution
 Today, we will focus on a particular distortion—ordeals.
Ordeals and Redistribution
 Today, we will focus on a particular distortion—ordeals.
 Ordeal: activity that is costly for the agent performing it but does
not directly benefit anyone. Examples:
Ordeals and Redistribution
 Today, we will focus on a particular distortion—ordeals.
 Ordeal: activity that is costly for the agent performing it but does
not directly benefit anyone. Examples:
 Waiting time
 Travel distance
 Filling out forms
 ...
Ordeals and Redistribution
 Today, we will focus on a particular distortion—ordeals.
 Ordeal: activity that is costly for the agent performing it but does
not directly benefit anyone. Examples:
 Waiting time
 Deshpande  Li (2019), Rose (2021), Zeckhauser (2021)
 Travel distance
 Alatas et al. (2016), Hernandez  Seira (2022)
 Filling out forms
 Deshpande  Li (2019), Finkelstein  Notowidigdo (2019)
 ...
Ordeals and Redistribution
 Today, we will focus on a particular distortion—ordeals.
 Ordeal: activity that is costly for the agent performing it but does
not directly benefit anyone. Examples:
 Waiting time
 Deshpande  Li (2019), Rose (2021), Zeckhauser (2021)
 Travel distance
 Alatas et al. (2016), Hernandez  Seira (2022)
 Filling out forms
 Deshpande  Li (2019), Finkelstein  Notowidigdo (2019)
 ...
 Nichols and Zeckhauser (1982): Ordeals as costly screening
devices.
Ordeals and Redistribution
 Today, we will focus on a particular distortion—ordeals.
 Ordeal: activity that is costly for the agent performing it but does
not directly benefit anyone. Examples:
 Waiting time
 Deshpande  Li (2019), Rose (2021), Zeckhauser (2021)
 Travel distance
 Alatas et al. (2016), Hernandez  Seira (2022)
 Filling out forms
 Deshpande  Li (2019), Finkelstein  Notowidigdo (2019)
 ...
 Nichols and Zeckhauser (1982): Ordeals as costly screening
devices.
 Welfare properties of ordeals are not very well understood.
Ordeals and Redistribution
 Ordeals are particularly useful when allocating money.
Ordeals and Redistribution
 Ordeals are particularly useful when allocating money.
 Governments often engage in direct in-cash redistribution.
Ordeals and Redistribution
 Ordeals are particularly useful when allocating money.
 Governments often engage in direct in-cash redistribution.
 Of course, governments use verifiable information to target.
Ordeals and Redistribution
 Ordeals are particularly useful when allocating money.
 Governments often engage in direct in-cash redistribution.
 Of course, governments use verifiable information to target.
 Should we also screen for unobserved characteristics?
Ordeals and Redistribution
 Ordeals are particularly useful when allocating money.
 Governments often engage in direct in-cash redistribution.
 Of course, governments use verifiable information to target.
 Should we also screen for unobserved characteristics?
 Two examples for contrast:
Ordeals and Redistribution
 Ordeals are particularly useful when allocating money.
 Governments often engage in direct in-cash redistribution.
 Of course, governments use verifiable information to target.
 Should we also screen for unobserved characteristics?
 Two examples for contrast:
 Direct cash subsidies in the US in Covid-19 pandemic;
Ordeals and Redistribution
 Ordeals are particularly useful when allocating money.
 Governments often engage in direct in-cash redistribution.
 Of course, governments use verifiable information to target.
 Should we also screen for unobserved characteristics?
 Two examples for contrast:
 Direct cash subsidies in the US in Covid-19 pandemic;
 Indonesia’s Conditional Cash Transfer Program.
Ordeals and Redistribution
 Ordeals are particularly useful when allocating money.
 Governments often engage in direct in-cash redistribution.
 Of course, governments use verifiable information to target.
 Should we also screen for unobserved characteristics?
 Two examples for contrast:
 Direct cash subsidies in the US in Covid-19 pandemic;
 Indonesia’s Conditional Cash Transfer Program.
 Should we use an ordeal?
Ordeals and Redistribution
 Ordeals are particularly useful when allocating money.
 Governments often engage in direct in-cash redistribution.
 Of course, governments use verifiable information to target.
 Should we also screen for unobserved characteristics?
 Two examples for contrast:
 Direct cash subsidies in the US in Covid-19 pandemic;
 Indonesia’s Conditional Cash Transfer Program.
 Should we use an ordeal?
 “Equity-efficiency trade-off in quasi-linear environments”
Ordeals and Redistribution
 Ordeals are particularly useful when allocating money.
 Governments often engage in direct in-cash redistribution.
 Of course, governments use verifiable information to target.
 Should we also screen for unobserved characteristics?
 Two examples for contrast:
 Direct cash subsidies in the US in Covid-19 pandemic;
 Indonesia’s Conditional Cash Transfer Program.
 Should we use an ordeal?
 “Equity-efficiency trade-off in quasi-linear environments”
 If yes, which ordeal to use?
Ordeals and Redistribution
 Ordeals are particularly useful when allocating money.
 Governments often engage in direct in-cash redistribution.
 Of course, governments use verifiable information to target.
 Should we also screen for unobserved characteristics?
 Two examples for contrast:
 Direct cash subsidies in the US in Covid-19 pandemic;
 Indonesia’s Conditional Cash Transfer Program.
 Should we use an ordeal?
 “Equity-efficiency trade-off in quasi-linear environments”
 If yes, which ordeal to use?
 “Comparison of Screening Devices” (with F. Yang and M. Akbarpour)
Note on literature
 It is well known that ordeals can improve targeting:
 McAfee  McMillan (1992), Hartline  Rouchgarden (2008), Condorelli
(2012), Chakravarty  Kaplan (2013), Yang (2023), ...
 Most of the theory work focused on efficiency as design goal
(allocation of goods other than money!)
 Moreover, all of these papers fix a screening device.
 Classical references:
 Weitzman (1977), Nichols  Zeckhauser (1982), Besley  Coate (1992),
Saez and Stantcheva (2016), ...
 Other papers on IMD:
 Condorelli (2013), Z. Kang (2020), M. Kang and Zheng (2020), Pai and
Strack (2022), ...
Paper #1
“Equity-efficiency trade-off in quasi-linear environments”
What I do
 I study a “pure” redistribution problem: How to allocate cash to
agents differing in their (privately-observed) marginal values for
money (welfare weights).
What I do
 I study a “pure” redistribution problem: How to allocate cash to
agents differing in their (privately-observed) marginal values for
money (welfare weights).
 Absent additional information, the only incentive-compatible
mechanism is a lump-sum transfer.
What I do
 I study a “pure” redistribution problem: How to allocate cash to
agents differing in their (privately-observed) marginal values for
money (welfare weights).
 Absent additional information, the only incentive-compatible
mechanism is a lump-sum transfer.
 But what if the designer can ask agents to burn utility (an
“ordeal mechanism”)?
What I do
 I study a “pure” redistribution problem: How to allocate cash to
agents differing in their (privately-observed) marginal values for
money (welfare weights).
 Absent additional information, the only incentive-compatible
mechanism is a lump-sum transfer.
 But what if the designer can ask agents to burn utility (an
“ordeal mechanism”)?
 Trade-off: Better targeting but lower efficiency.
What I do
 I study a “pure” redistribution problem: How to allocate cash to
agents differing in their (privately-observed) marginal values for
money (welfare weights).
 Absent additional information, the only incentive-compatible
mechanism is a lump-sum transfer.
 But what if the designer can ask agents to burn utility (an
“ordeal mechanism”)?
 Trade-off: Better targeting but lower efficiency.
 Main result: A condition for optimality of using an ordeal.
What I do
 I study a “pure” redistribution problem: How to allocate cash to
agents differing in their (privately-observed) marginal values for
money (welfare weights).
 Absent additional information, the only incentive-compatible
mechanism is a lump-sum transfer.
 But what if the designer can ask agents to burn utility (an
“ordeal mechanism”)?
 Trade-off: Better targeting but lower efficiency.
 Main result: A condition for optimality of using an ordeal.
 Simple intuition.
Model
Model
Model
 Designer has a budget B of money that she allocates to a unit
mass of agents.
Model
 Designer has a budget B of money that she allocates to a unit
mass of agents.
 Each agent has a “marginal value for money” v that is the
agent’s private information (this is just a welfare weight, as in
Saez and Stantcheva, 2016)
Model
 Designer has a budget B of money that she allocates to a unit
mass of agents.
 Each agent has a “marginal value for money” v that is the
agent’s private information (this is just a welfare weight, as in
Saez and Stantcheva, 2016)
 The designer knows the distribution and maximizes total value.
Model
 Designer has a budget B of money that she allocates to a unit
mass of agents.
 Each agent has a “marginal value for money” v that is the
agent’s private information (this is just a welfare weight, as in
Saez and Stantcheva, 2016)
 The designer knows the distribution and maximizes total value.
 Wlog, designer has no additional information.
Model
 Designer has a budget B of money that she allocates to a unit
mass of agents.
 Each agent has a “marginal value for money” v that is the
agent’s private information (this is just a welfare weight, as in
Saez and Stantcheva, 2016)
 The designer knows the distribution and maximizes total value.
 Wlog, designer has no additional information.
 The value of giving a lump-sum transfer is simply E[v] B.
Model
 Designer has a budget B of money that she allocates to a unit
mass of agents.
 Each agent has a “marginal value for money” v that is the
agent’s private information (this is just a welfare weight, as in
Saez and Stantcheva, 2016)
 The designer knows the distribution and maximizes total value.
 Wlog, designer has no additional information.
 The value of giving a lump-sum transfer is simply E[v] B.
 I normalize E[v] = 1 (the “marginal value of public funds”).
Model
 Suppose the designer can ask agents to “burn utility”:
Complete a task that is publicly observable, costly to the agent,
and socially wasteful (an “ordeal”).
Model
 Suppose the designer can ask agents to “burn utility”:
Complete a task that is publicly observable, costly to the agent,
and socially wasteful (an “ordeal”).
 The designer can choose a difficulty level y 2 [0; 1].
Model
 Suppose the designer can ask agents to “burn utility”:
Complete a task that is publicly observable, costly to the agent,
and socially wasteful (an “ordeal”).
 The designer can choose a difficulty level y 2 [0; 1].
 Each agent has a privately-observed cost c.
Model
 Suppose the designer can ask agents to “burn utility”:
Complete a task that is publicly observable, costly to the agent,
and socially wasteful (an “ordeal”).
 The designer can choose a difficulty level y 2 [0; 1].
 Each agent has a privately-observed cost c.
 Utility of each agent is quasi-linear:
cy + vt;
when completing ordeal y and receiving a transfer t.
Model
 Suppose the designer can ask agents to “burn utility”:
Complete a task that is publicly observable, costly to the agent,
and socially wasteful (an “ordeal”).
 The designer can choose a difficulty level y 2 [0; 1].
 Each agent has a privately-observed cost c.
 Utility of each agent is quasi-linear:
cy + vt;
when completing ordeal y and receiving a transfer t.
 Cost c measured in “social-utility units;” let k  c=v be the cost
measured in money— only k matters for agents’ choices.
Model
 Suppose the designer can ask agents to “burn utility”:
Complete a task that is publicly observable, costly to the agent,
and socially wasteful (an “ordeal”).
 The designer can choose a difficulty level y 2 [0; 1].
 Each agent has a privately-observed cost c.
 Utility of each agent is quasi-linear:
cy + vt;
when completing ordeal y and receiving a transfer t.
 Cost c measured in “social-utility units;” let k  c=v be the cost
measured in money— only k matters for agents’ choices.
 Assume k  F with C1 density f on [k; k̄] with k = 0, f(k)  0.
Model
 The designer now maximizes
E[ cy(k) + vt(k)]
subject to budget constraint and incentive-compatibility
(self-selection based on k).
Model
 The designer now maximizes
E[ cy(k) + vt(k)]
subject to budget constraint and incentive-compatibility
(self-selection based on k).
 Note: Any positive level of y is a pure social waste.
Model
 The designer now maximizes
E[ cy(k) + vt(k)]
subject to budget constraint and incentive-compatibility
(self-selection based on k).
 Note: Any positive level of y is a pure social waste.
 If no redistributive preferences (all v = 1), then trivially lump-sum
payment is optimal.
Model
 The designer now maximizes
E[ cy(k) + vt(k)]
subject to budget constraint and incentive-compatibility
(self-selection based on k).
 Note: Any positive level of y is a pure social waste.
 If no redistributive preferences (all v = 1), then trivially lump-sum
payment is optimal.
 But in general, there is an equity-efficiency trade-off.
Analysis
Analysis
Analysis
 Suppose that the designer offers an additional payment t0 for an
ordeal y0  0.
Analysis
 Suppose that the designer offers an additional payment t0 for an
ordeal y0  0.
 Agents with k  t0=y0 accept.
Analysis
 Suppose that the designer offers an additional payment t0 for an
ordeal y0  0.
 Agents with k  t0=y0 accept.
 Let
E
h
vjc
v
= k
i
be the conditional expectation of v conditional on the relative
cost being equal to k (assumed continuous).
Analysis
 Suppose that the designer offers an additional payment t0 for an
ordeal y0  0.
 Agents with k  t0=y0 accept.
 Let
E
h
vjc
v
= k
i
be the conditional expectation of v conditional on the relative
cost being equal to k (assumed continuous).
 E[vjk] measures targeting effectiveness.
Analysis
 Suppose that the designer offers an additional payment t0 for an
ordeal y0  0.
 Agents with k  t0=y0 accept.
 Let
E
h
vjc
v
= k
i
be the conditional expectation of v conditional on the relative
cost being equal to k (assumed continuous).
 E[vjk] measures targeting effectiveness.
 Designer’s payoff from this “ordeal mechanism:”
Z t0=y0
0
E[vjk] (t0 ky0)f(k)dk + (B t0F(t0=y0)):
Analysis
 We want to check whether the ordeal mechanism strictly
outperforms the lump-sum transfer for small t0 = y0:
Z 
0
E[vjk]( k)f(k)dk  F():
Analysis
 We want to check whether the ordeal mechanism strictly
outperforms the lump-sum transfer for small t0 = y0:
Z 
0
E[vjk]( k)f(k)dk  F():
 Enough to prove that the ratio of the RHS to LHS is above 1 in
the limit:
lim
!0
R 
0 E[vjk]( k)f(k)dk
F()
(h)
= lim
!0
R 
0 E[vjk]f(k)dk
f() + F()
(h)
=
E[vjk]
2
;
by L’Hôpital’s rule.
Analysis
 We want to check whether the ordeal mechanism strictly
outperforms the lump-sum transfer for small t0 = y0:
Z 
0
E[vjk]( k)f(k)dk  F():
 Enough to prove that the ratio of the RHS to LHS is above 1 in
the limit:
lim
!0
R 
0 E[vjk]( k)f(k)dk
F()
(h)
= lim
!0
R 
0 E[vjk]f(k)dk
f() + F()
(h)
=
E[vjk]
2
;
by L’Hôpital’s rule.
 So ordeal is better than lump-sum when E[vjk]  2.
Analysis
Proposition
If the expected value for money conditional on the lowest relative cost
exceeds the value of public funds by more than a factor of two, i.e., if
E[vjk]  2; (?)
then the ordeal mechanism strictly outperforms giving a lump-sum
transfer for some positive   0.
Analysis
Proposition
If the expected value for money conditional on the lowest relative cost
exceeds the value of public funds by more than a factor of two, i.e., if
E[vjk]  2; (?)
then the ordeal mechanism strictly outperforms giving a lump-sum
transfer for some positive   0.
Intuitively: Using an ordeal becomes optimal when redistributive
preferences are strong enough and targeting effectiveness is high.
Why 2?
 Similar condition arises in papers studying optimal market design
under redistributive preferences.
Why 2?
 Similar condition arises in papers studying optimal market design
under redistributive preferences.
 DKA (2021): When designing a goods market, rationing may be
optimal when the expected welfare weight conditional on the
lowest willingness to pay for the good exceeds the average
welfare weight by more than a factor of two.
Why 2?
 Similar condition arises in papers studying optimal market design
under redistributive preferences.
 DKA (2021): When designing a goods market, rationing may be
optimal when the expected welfare weight conditional on the
lowest willingness to pay for the good exceeds the average
welfare weight by more than a factor of two.
 Versions of this condition (with “2”) keep coming up:
Why 2?
 Similar condition arises in papers studying optimal market design
under redistributive preferences.
 DKA (2021): When designing a goods market, rationing may be
optimal when the expected welfare weight conditional on the
lowest willingness to pay for the good exceeds the average
welfare weight by more than a factor of two.
 Versions of this condition (with “2”) keep coming up:
 Z. Kang (2020);
Why 2?
 Similar condition arises in papers studying optimal market design
under redistributive preferences.
 DKA (2021): When designing a goods market, rationing may be
optimal when the expected welfare weight conditional on the
lowest willingness to pay for the good exceeds the average
welfare weight by more than a factor of two.
 Versions of this condition (with “2”) keep coming up:
 Z. Kang (2020);
 M. Kang and Zheng (2020);
Why 2?
 Similar condition arises in papers studying optimal market design
under redistributive preferences.
 DKA (2021): When designing a goods market, rationing may be
optimal when the expected welfare weight conditional on the
lowest willingness to pay for the good exceeds the average
welfare weight by more than a factor of two.
 Versions of this condition (with “2”) keep coming up:
 Z. Kang (2020);
 M. Kang and Zheng (2020);
 Pai and Strack (2022);
Why 2?
 Similar condition arises in papers studying optimal market design
under redistributive preferences.
 DKA (2021): When designing a goods market, rationing may be
optimal when the expected welfare weight conditional on the
lowest willingness to pay for the good exceeds the average
welfare weight by more than a factor of two.
 Versions of this condition (with “2”) keep coming up:
 Z. Kang (2020);
 M. Kang and Zheng (2020);
 Pai and Strack (2022);
 ADK (2023).
Why 2?
 Similar condition arises in papers studying optimal market design
under redistributive preferences.
 DKA (2021): When designing a goods market, rationing may be
optimal when the expected welfare weight conditional on the
lowest willingness to pay for the good exceeds the average
welfare weight by more than a factor of two.
 Versions of this condition (with “2”) keep coming up:
 Z. Kang (2020);
 M. Kang and Zheng (2020);
 Pai and Strack (2022);
 ADK (2023).
 Why “2”?
Analysis
Proposition
If the expected value for money conditional on the lowest relative cost
exceeds the value of public funds by more than a factor of two, i.e., if
E[vjk]  2; (?)
then the ordeal mechanism strictly outperforms giving a lump-sum
transfer for some positive   0.
High-level intuition:
 Better targeting requires sacrificing some surplus.
Analysis
Proposition
If the expected value for money conditional on the lowest relative cost
exceeds the value of public funds by more than a factor of two, i.e., if
E[vjk]  2; (?)
then the ordeal mechanism strictly outperforms giving a lump-sum
transfer for some positive   0.
High-level intuition:
 Better targeting requires sacrificing some surplus.
 For every dollar of public funds spent, only 1=2 of the dollar is
received by an agent (the other half is “burned” in screening).
Analysis
Proposition
If the expected value for money conditional on the lowest relative cost
exceeds the value of public funds by more than a factor of two, i.e., if
E[vjk]  2; (?)
then the ordeal mechanism strictly outperforms giving a lump-sum
transfer for some positive   0.
High-level intuition:
 Better targeting requires sacrificing some surplus.
 For every dollar of public funds spent, only 1=2 of the dollar is
received by an agent (the other half is “burned” in screening).
 Thus, ordeal is better if the designer values each dollar given to
lowest-cost agent at 2 or more.
Why 2?
Why 2?
Why 2?
Why 2?
Why 2?
Why 2?
Why 2?
Optimal mechanism
Is this intuition robust to choosing the optimal mechanism?
Optimal mechanism
Is this intuition robust to choosing the optimal mechanism?
max
y(k)2[0; 1]; t(k)0
Z k̄
k
E[vjk]( ky(k) + t(k))dF(k); (OBJ)
ky(k) + t(k)  ky(k0) + t(k0); 8k; k0; (IC)
ky(k) + t(k)  0; 8k; (IR)
Z k̄
k
t(k)dF(k) = B: (B)
Optimal mechanism
Proposition
The optimal mechanism uses an ordeal (y is strictly positive for some
agents) if and only if
E[V(k)jk  k0]  0 for some k0; (??)
where
V(k) =

E
h
vjc
v
 k
i
1
 F(k)
f(k)
k: (V)
Optimal mechanism
Proposition
The optimal mechanism uses an ordeal (y is strictly positive for some
agents) if and only if
E[V(k)jk  k0]  0 for some k0; (??)
where
V(k) =

E
h
vjc
v
 k
i
1
 F(k)
f(k)
k: (V)
Condition (?) implies that V(k)  0 for small enough k; hence,
condition (?) implies condition (??).
Optimal mechanism
Proposition
The optimal mechanism uses an ordeal (y is strictly positive for some
agents) if and only if
E[V(k)jk  k0]  0 for some k0; (??)
where
V(k) =

E
h
vjc
v
 k
i
1
 F(k)
f(k)
k: (V)
Condition (?) implies that V(k)  0 for small enough k; hence,
condition (?) implies condition (??).
Conversely, when V(k) is quasi-concave, condition (??) implies that
condition (?) must hold as a weak inequality.
Optimal mechanism
Proposition (continued)
When B is large enough, the optimal mechanism offers a single
payment k?
for completing the ordeal y = 1, and allocates the
remaining budget as a lump-sum payment.
Optimal mechanism
Proposition (continued)
When B is large enough, the optimal mechanism offers a single
payment k?
for completing the ordeal y = 1, and allocates the
remaining budget as a lump-sum payment.
Intuition:
 Because I assumed k = 0, we have V(0) = 0.
Optimal mechanism
Proposition (continued)
When B is large enough, the optimal mechanism offers a single
payment k?
for completing the ordeal y = 1, and allocates the
remaining budget as a lump-sum payment.
Intuition:
 Because I assumed k = 0, we have V(0) = 0.
 Turns out that condition (?) is equivalent to V0(0)  0.
Optimal mechanism
Proposition (continued)
When B is large enough, the optimal mechanism offers a single
payment k?
for completing the ordeal y = 1, and allocates the
remaining budget as a lump-sum payment.
Intuition:
 Because I assumed k = 0, we have V(0) = 0.
 Turns out that condition (?) is equivalent to V0(0)  0.
 This condition is (almost) necessary if V is quasi-concave.
Concluding remarks
Concluding remarks
Concluding remarks
 Looked at a simple(st?) equity-efficiency problem.
Concluding remarks
 Looked at a simple(st?) equity-efficiency problem.
 Condition with factor 2 reflects a fundamental equity-efficiency
trade-off in quasi-linear environments.
Concluding remarks
 Looked at a simple(st?) equity-efficiency problem.
 Condition with factor 2 reflects a fundamental equity-efficiency
trade-off in quasi-linear environments.
 The condition is still sufficient without quasi-linearity in money!
Concluding remarks
 Looked at a simple(st?) equity-efficiency problem.
 Condition with factor 2 reflects a fundamental equity-efficiency
trade-off in quasi-linear environments.
 The condition is still sufficient without quasi-linearity in money!
 Importance of the assumption k = 0 ! policy implications.
Concluding remarks
 Looked at a simple(st?) equity-efficiency problem.
 Condition with factor 2 reflects a fundamental equity-efficiency
trade-off in quasi-linear environments.
 The condition is still sufficient without quasi-linearity in money!
 Importance of the assumption k = 0 ! policy implications.
 Results silent about which ordeal to use.
Paper #2
“Comparison of Screening Devices”
(with Frank Yang and Mohammad Akbarpour)
Motivation
Many allocations use costly screening devices:
 Waiting time;
 Filling out forms;
 Travel distance ;
 ...
For example:
 Imposing an ordeal of traveling to a registration site improves
targeting in Indonesia’s Conditional Cash Transfer program
(Alatas et al. 2016)
 Level of congestion at Social Security Administration field offices
affects targeting of disability programs (Deshpande  Li 2019)
This paper: What makes one screening device better than another?
Illustrative Example
Illustrative Example
Illustrative Example
Allocate mass 2=3 of money to a unit
mass of agents, each receiving 1.
 Types: p(oor), m(iddle class), r(ich)
 Welfare weights: v = 3, 1, and 0
kA kB v
p 1 2  3
m 1  2 1
r 1 1 0
Screening devices A and B: kA and kB are per-unit-of-difficulty costs.
Illustrative Example
Allocate mass 2=3 of money to a unit
mass of agents, each receiving 1.
 Types: p(oor), m(iddle class), r(ich)
 Welfare weights: v = 3, 1, and 0
kA kB v
p 1 2  3
m 1  2 1
r 1 1 0
Screening devices A and B: kA and kB are per-unit-of-difficulty costs.
Screening device A achieves perfect targeting...
Illustrative Example
Allocate mass 2=3 of money to a unit
mass of agents, each receiving 1.
 Types: p(oor), m(iddle class), r(ich)
 Welfare weights: v = 3, 1, and 0
kA kB v
p 1 2  3
m 1  2 1
r 1 1 0
Screening devices A and B: kA and kB are per-unit-of-difficulty costs.
Screening device A achieves perfect targeting... but screening
device B is better than A!
Illustrative Example
Allocate mass 2=3 of money to a unit
mass of agents, each receiving 1.
 Types: p(oor), m(iddle class), r(ich)
 Welfare weights: v = 3, 1, and 0
kA kB v
p 1 2  3
m 1  2 1
r 1 1 0
Screening devices A and B: kA and kB are per-unit-of-difficulty costs.
Screening device A achieves perfect targeting... but screening
device B is better than A!
 Under A, “market-clearing” difficulty = 1 unit.
Total welfare = 1
3 (3 (2) + 1 ) = 7
3 
 Under B, “market-clearing” difficulty = 1
2 unit.
Total welfare = 1
3 (3 (1 1
2) + 0 0) = 1 1
2
Illustrative Example
Allocate mass 2=3 of money to a unit
mass of agents, each receiving 1.
 Types: p(oor), m(iddle class), r(ich)
 Welfare weights: v = 3, 1, and 0
kA kB v
p 1 2  3
m 1  2 1
r 1 1 0
Screening devices A and B: kA and kB are per-unit-of-difficulty costs.
Screening device A achieves perfect targeting... but screening
device B is better than A!
 Screening device B is worse at targeting but provides higher
rents to agents conditional on allocation.
 kB has lower correlation with v but it has higher dispersion.
Framework
Framework
Costly Screening—framework
 A screening device D is a conditional distribution
D : v ! ∆(R++):
Costly Screening—framework
 A screening device D is a conditional distribution
D : v ! ∆(R++):
 Interpretation: D(v) is the distribution of per-unit-of-difficulty
costs k for agents with welfare weight v.
Costly Screening—framework
 A screening device D is a conditional distribution
D : v ! ∆(R++):
 Interpretation: D(v) is the distribution of per-unit-of-difficulty
costs k for agents with welfare weight v.
 This allows us to vary the screening device while holding fixed
designer’s redistributive preferences.
Costly Screening—framework
 A screening device D is a conditional distribution
D : v ! ∆(R++):
 Interpretation: D(v) is the distribution of per-unit-of-difficulty
costs k for agents with welfare weight v.
 This allows us to vary the screening device while holding fixed
designer’s redistributive preferences.
 Given D, denote by F the cumulative distribution function of k.
Costly Screening—framework
 A screening device D is a conditional distribution
D : v ! ∆(R++):
 Interpretation: D(v) is the distribution of per-unit-of-difficulty
costs k for agents with welfare weight v.
 This allows us to vary the screening device while holding fixed
designer’s redistributive preferences.
 Given D, denote by F the cumulative distribution function of k.
 Screening device identified by the joint distribution of (v; k).
Costly Screening—framework
 A screening device D is a conditional distribution
D : v ! ∆(R++):
 Interpretation: D(v) is the distribution of per-unit-of-difficulty
costs k for agents with welfare weight v.
 This allows us to vary the screening device while holding fixed
designer’s redistributive preferences.
 Given D, denote by F the cumulative distribution function of k.
 Screening device identified by the joint distribution of (v; k).
 Normalize the maximal quantity of money received by agent to 1;
budget B 2 [0; 1]; no restrictions on difficulty y  0.
Costly Screening—framework
In the paper:
 Allocation of goods with heterogeneous quality q 2 [0; 1].
Costly Screening—framework
In the paper:
 Allocation of goods with heterogeneous quality q 2 [0; 1].
 Each agent has a private value w for the good and welfare
weight v.
Costly Screening—framework
In the paper:
 Allocation of goods with heterogeneous quality q 2 [0; 1].
 Each agent has a private value w for the good and welfare
weight v.
 Screening device D maps (v; w) into distribution of costs k.
Costly Screening—framework
In the paper:
 Allocation of goods with heterogeneous quality q 2 [0; 1].
 Each agent has a private value w for the good and welfare
weight v.
 Screening device D maps (v; w) into distribution of costs k.
 Utility is wq ky, contribution to social welfare is v(wq ky).
Costly Screening—framework
In the paper:
 Allocation of goods with heterogeneous quality q 2 [0; 1].
 Each agent has a private value w for the good and welfare
weight v.
 Screening device D maps (v; w) into distribution of costs k.
 Utility is wq ky, contribution to social welfare is v(wq ky).
 Marginal rate of substitution: r = w=k.
Costly Screening—framework
In the paper:
 Allocation of goods with heterogeneous quality q 2 [0; 1].
 Each agent has a private value w for the good and welfare
weight v.
 Screening device D maps (v; w) into distribution of costs k.
 Utility is wq ky, contribution to social welfare is v(wq ky).
 Marginal rate of substitution: r = w=k.
 All results apply if we replace the distribution of inverse costs 1=k
with the distribution of the marginal rate of substitution.
Designing an ideal screening device?
Allocate supply B of money to agents with welfare weights distributed
uniformly: v  U[0;1].
Designing an ideal screening device?
Allocate supply B of money to agents with welfare weights distributed
uniformly: v  U[0;1].
The following screening device achieves the first best: k = 1fv1 Bg.
Designing an ideal screening device?
Allocate supply B of money to agents with welfare weights distributed
uniformly: v  U[0;1].
The following screening device achieves the first best: k = 1fv1 Bg.
Not practical:
 cannot freely design screening devices;
 sensitive to the available supply level.
Comparing Screening Devices
Screening device D1 dominates screening device D2 if
OPT(D1;B)  OPT(D2;B)
for every supply level B 2 [0;1], where
 OPT(D;B) is the social welfare induced by the optimal
allocation mechanism given screening device D and budget B.
Comparing Screening Devices
Screening device D1 dominates screening device D2 if
OPT(D1;B)  OPT(D2;B)
for every supply level B 2 [0;1], where
 OPT(D;B) is the social welfare induced by the optimal
allocation mechanism given screening device D and budget B.
Question: When does one screening device dominate another?
Comparing Screening Devices
Screening device D1 dominates screening device D2 if
OPT(D1;B)  OPT(D2;B)
for every supply level B 2 [0;1], where
 OPT(D;B) is the social welfare induced by the optimal
allocation mechanism given screening device D and budget B.
Question: When does one screening device dominate another?
Remark: While we focus on optimal mechanisms, our results also
hold with “market mechanisms” (demand = supply).
Main Results
Main Results
Characterization of Dominance
For any screening device D, define its welfare index at parameter s:
W(D;s) :=
Z s
0

1
F 1(t)
F 1(s)

| {z }
Rent Provision
 E
h
v j k = F 1
(t)
i
| {z }
Targeting Effectiveness
dt:
Characterization of Dominance
For any screening device D, define its welfare index at parameter s:
W(D;s) :=
Z s
0

1
F 1(t)
F 1(s)

| {z }
Rent Provision
 E
h
v j k = F 1
(t)
i
| {z }
Targeting Effectiveness
dt:
Rent provision:
 utility net of screening costs for an agent whose cost is in the
bottom t quantile, given supply s;
 measured in units of money.
Characterization of Dominance
For any screening device D, define its welfare index at parameter s:
W(D;s) :=
Z s
0

1
F 1(t)
F 1(s)

| {z }
Rent Provision
 E
h
v j k = F 1
(t)
i
| {z }
Targeting Effectiveness
dt:
Rent provision:
 utility net of screening costs for an agent whose cost is in the
bottom t quantile, given supply s;
 measured in units of money.
Targeting effectiveness:
 converts monetary units to social welfare units;
 uses information revealed through agent’s cost k.
Characterization of Dominance
For any screening device D, define its welfare index at parameter s:
W(D;s) :=
Z s
0

1
F 1(t)
F 1(s)

| {z }
Rent Provision
 E
h
v j k = F 1
(t)
i
| {z }
Targeting Effectiveness
dt:
Theorem 1
For any two screening devices D1 and D2, if
W(D1;s)  W(D2;s); for all s 2 [0;1]; (?)
then screening device D1 dominates screening device D2.
Characterization of Dominance
For any screening device D, define its welfare index at parameter s:
W(D;s) :=
Z s
0

1
F 1(t)
F 1(s)

| {z }
Rent Provision
 E
h
v j k = F 1
(t)
i
| {z }
Targeting Effectiveness
dt:
Theorem 1
For any two screening devices D1 and D2, if
W(D1;s)  W(D2;s); for all s 2 [0;1]; (?)
then screening device D1 dominates screening device D2.
Remark: A weakening of (?) is both necessary and sufficient
Math Break: Two Notions of Spread
Dispersive order: For two random variables X and Y with CDFs
FX and FY , X disp Y if
F 1
X (t) F 1
X (s)  F 1
Y (t) F 1
Y (s); for all 0  s  t  1:
Math Break: Two Notions of Spread
Dispersive order: For two random variables X and Y with CDFs
FX and FY , X disp Y if
F 1
X (t) F 1
X (s)  F 1
Y (t) F 1
Y (s); for all 0  s  t  1:
Majorization order: For two functions h1 and h2 on [0;1], h2 maj h1
if
Z s
0
h2(t)dt 
Z s
0
h1(t)dt; for all s 2 [0; 1], with equality at s = 1.
If h1;h2 are non-decreasing, then this is the same as
h2(U) mps h1(U) ;
where mps is mean-preserving spread and U is a uniform random
variable.
Dispersion and Correlation
Let V(t) := E[v j k = F 1(t)] be the posterior mean of v when k is
equal to its quantile t.
Theorem 2
For any two screening devices D1 and D2, if
(i) log(k2) disp log(k1),
(ii) V2 maj V1,
then screening device D1 dominates screening device D2.
Dispersion and Correlation
Let V(t) := E[v j k = F 1(t)] be the posterior mean of v when k is
equal to its quantile t.
Theorem 2
For any two screening devices D1 and D2, if
(i) log(k2) disp log(k1),
(ii) V2 maj V1,
then screening device D1 dominates screening device D2.
 Condition (i): marginal distribution of k
 Condition (ii): correlation of v and k
Dispersion and Correlation
Let V(t) := E[v j k = F 1(t)] be the posterior mean of v when k is
equal to its quantile t.
Theorem 2
For any two screening devices D1 and D2, if
(i) log(k2) disp log(k1),
(ii) V2 maj V1,
then screening device D1 dominates screening device D2.
 Condition (i): marginal distribution of k
 Condition (ii): correlation of v and k
Dispersion and Correlation
Let V(t) := E[v j k = F 1(t)] be the posterior mean of v when k is
equal to its quantile t.
Theorem 2
For any two screening devices D1 and D2, if
(i) log(k2) disp log(k1),
(ii) V2 maj V1,
then screening device D1 dominates screening device D2.
 Condition (i): marginal distribution of k
 Condition (ii): correlation of v and k
 Dispersion at log level for k () Rent provision
 Negative correlation of (v;k) () Targeting effectiveness
Economic Implications
Economic Implications
Limits of Costly Screening
Proposition 1
For any   0, there exists a screening device D such that, for any
budget B, D achieves welfare that is within  of the first-best welfare.
Limits of Costly Screening
Proposition 1
For any   0, there exists a screening device D such that, for any
budget B, D achieves welfare that is within  of the first-best welfare.
D approximates the first-best robustly for all budget levels!
Limits of Costly Screening
Proposition 1
For any   0, there exists a screening device D such that, for any
budget B, D achieves welfare that is within  of the first-best welfare.
D approximates the first-best robustly for all budget levels!
Proof sketch:
Limits of Costly Screening
Proposition 1
For any   0, there exists a screening device D such that, for any
budget B, D achieves welfare that is within  of the first-best welfare.
D approximates the first-best robustly for all budget levels!
Proof sketch:
 Perfect targeting: make k a strictly decreasing function of v.
 Increasingly dispersed: make log(k) increasingly dispersed as 
decreases.
Limits of Costly Screening
Proposition 2
For any device D and any   0, there exists D such that:
(i) D has better targeting effectiveness than D: V maj V;
(ii) For any budget B, D achieves social welfare that is less than 
under the market-clearing rule.
Limits of Costly Screening
Proposition 2
For any device D and any   0, there exists D such that:
(i) D has better targeting effectiveness than D: V maj V;
(ii) For any budget B, D achieves social welfare that is less than 
under the market-clearing rule.
Proof sketch:
 D can be made to achieve perfect targeting;
 But if log(k) is increasingly compressed then we have arbitrarily
low welfare.
Importance of Dispersion
Proposition 3
Consider any screening devices D; D1; D2; D3 such that
k1 = k ∆; k2 = min(k;∆0); k3 = ∆00k;
for some constants ∆;∆0; ∆00  0. Then
 D1 dominates D;
 D dominates D2;
 D is equivalent to D3.
Importance of Dispersion
Proposition 3
Consider any screening devices D; D1; D2; D3 such that
k1 = k ∆; k2 = min(k;∆0); k3 = ∆00k;
for some constants ∆;∆0; ∆00  0. Then
 D1 dominates D;
 D dominates D2;
 D is equivalent to D3.
Even though both D1; D2; D3 reduce the level of costs,
 uniformly decreasing costs is welfare-enhancing;
 allowing delegation of the task is welfare-reducing.
 multiplying costs by a constant is welfare-neutral.
Simple Regression Test
Proposition 4
If two screening devices D1 and D2 satisfy
log(k2) = log(k1) + ;
for some 2 [0;1] and random variable  that is independent of
(v;k1), then D1 dominates D2.
Simple Regression Test
Proposition 4
If two screening devices D1 and D2 satisfy
log(k2) = log(k1) + ;
for some 2 [0;1] and random variable  that is independent of
(v;k1), then D1 dominates D2.
D1 and D2 sort agents the same way up to idiosyncratic shocks:
 Smaller means less dispersion on the log level;
Simple Regression Test
Proposition 4
If two screening devices D1 and D2 satisfy
log(k2) = log(k1) + ;
for some 2 [0;1] and random variable  that is independent of
(v;k1), then D1 dominates D2.
D1 and D2 sort agents the same way up to idiosyncratic shocks:
 Smaller means less dispersion on the log level;
  introduces a trade-off between dispersion and targeting;
Simple Regression Test
Proposition 4
If two screening devices D1 and D2 satisfy
log(k2) = log(k1) + ;
for some 2 [0;1] and random variable  that is independent of
(v;k1), then D1 dominates D2.
D1 and D2 sort agents the same way up to idiosyncratic shocks:
 Smaller means less dispersion on the log level;
  introduces a trade-off between dispersion and targeting;
 Adding idiosyncratic noise makes screening device worse;
Simple Regression Test
Proposition 4
If two screening devices D1 and D2 satisfy
log(k2) = log(k1) + ;
for some 2 [0;1] and random variable  that is independent of
(v;k1), then D1 dominates D2.
D1 and D2 sort agents the same way up to idiosyncratic shocks:
 Smaller means less dispersion on the log level;
  introduces a trade-off between dispersion and targeting;
 Adding idiosyncratic noise makes screening device worse;
 Intuitively, we want variation in log(k) across (not within)
groups of different v.
Combining Screening Devices
For any two screening devices D1 and D2, either:
 Bundle two devices: Induce a new device D3 by
c3 = c1 + c2;
 Offer a choice: Induce a new device D3 by
c3 = min
n
c1;c2
o
:
Combining Screening Devices
For any two screening devices D1 and D2, either:
 Bundle two devices: Induce a new device D3 by
c3 = c1 + c2;
 Offer a choice: Induce a new device D3 by
c3 = min
n
c1;c2
o
:
Proposition 5
If D1 and D2 satisfy c2 = (c1;), where
  is independent of (v;c1);
 0  d log (c;)
d log c  1 for all c, almost surely in ;
then D1 dominates D3.
Concluding remarks
Concluding remarks
Concluding Remarks
What makes a costly screening device better than another?
 Two channels:
Concluding Remarks
What makes a costly screening device better than another?
 Two channels:
 rent provision;
Concluding Remarks
What makes a costly screening device better than another?
 Two channels:
 rent provision;
 targeting effectiveness.
Concluding Remarks
What makes a costly screening device better than another?
 Two channels:
 rent provision;
 targeting effectiveness.
 Characterized by:
Concluding Remarks
What makes a costly screening device better than another?
 Two channels:
 rent provision;
 targeting effectiveness.
 Characterized by:
 dispersion of the distribution of costs,
Concluding Remarks
What makes a costly screening device better than another?
 Two channels:
 rent provision;
 targeting effectiveness.
 Characterized by:
 dispersion of the distribution of costs,
 correlation of costs and welfare weights.
Concluding Remarks
What makes a costly screening device better than another?
 Two channels:
 rent provision;
 targeting effectiveness.
 Characterized by:
 dispersion of the distribution of costs,
 correlation of costs and welfare weights.
 Future directions:
Concluding Remarks
What makes a costly screening device better than another?
 Two channels:
 rent provision;
 targeting effectiveness.
 Characterized by:
 dispersion of the distribution of costs,
 correlation of costs and welfare weights.
 Future directions:
 “Useful” ordeals? (Kleven  Kopczuk, 2011, Dréze, 2019)
Concluding Remarks
What makes a costly screening device better than another?
 Two channels:
 rent provision;
 targeting effectiveness.
 Characterized by:
 dispersion of the distribution of costs,
 correlation of costs and welfare weights.
 Future directions:
 “Useful” ordeals? (Kleven  Kopczuk, 2011, Dréze, 2019)
 Ethical ramifications?
Concluding Remarks
What makes a costly screening device better than another?
 Two channels:
 rent provision;
 targeting effectiveness.
 Characterized by:
 dispersion of the distribution of costs,
 correlation of costs and welfare weights.
 Future directions:
 “Useful” ordeals? (Kleven  Kopczuk, 2011, Dréze, 2019)
 Ethical ramifications?
 Interaction with other tools for redistribution? (Ooghe, 2021)

More Related Content

Similar to Slides.pdf

R. sudarshan, public sector adaptation to pandemic era uncertainty some lesso...
R. sudarshan, public sector adaptation to pandemic era uncertainty some lesso...R. sudarshan, public sector adaptation to pandemic era uncertainty some lesso...
R. sudarshan, public sector adaptation to pandemic era uncertainty some lesso...KutsiyatinMSi
 
Redistribution through Markets
Redistribution through MarketsRedistribution through Markets
Redistribution through MarketsGRAPE
 
Rethink x+humanity+report
Rethink x+humanity+reportRethink x+humanity+report
Rethink x+humanity+reportAmérico Roque
 
9 principal unlocking the future of capital markets
9 principal unlocking the future of capital markets9 principal unlocking the future of capital markets
9 principal unlocking the future of capital markets123jumpad
 
Emerging Consumer Survey 2015 (9 Key Countries Emerging Economies: Brazil, Ch...
Emerging Consumer Survey 2015 (9 Key Countries Emerging Economies: Brazil, Ch...Emerging Consumer Survey 2015 (9 Key Countries Emerging Economies: Brazil, Ch...
Emerging Consumer Survey 2015 (9 Key Countries Emerging Economies: Brazil, Ch...Henky Hendranantha
 
emerging-consumer-survey-2015
emerging-consumer-survey-2015emerging-consumer-survey-2015
emerging-consumer-survey-2015Ashlee Ramanathan
 
Help Me Write My Essay For Free
Help Me Write My Essay For FreeHelp Me Write My Essay For Free
Help Me Write My Essay For FreeEmily Garcia
 
Continuing Resolution
Continuing ResolutionContinuing Resolution
Continuing ResolutionJulie Brown
 
Future Agenda 20 Insights For 2020 Final
Future Agenda   20 Insights For 2020   FinalFuture Agenda   20 Insights For 2020   Final
Future Agenda 20 Insights For 2020 FinalFuture Agenda
 
Regional Economic Blocks, Regional Public Goods and Development
Regional Economic Blocks, Regional Public Goods and DevelopmentRegional Economic Blocks, Regional Public Goods and Development
Regional Economic Blocks, Regional Public Goods and DevelopmentEconomic Research Forum
 
Consumer Wealth and Spending: The $12 Trillion Opportunity (2012)
Consumer Wealth and Spending: The $12 Trillion Opportunity (2012)Consumer Wealth and Spending: The $12 Trillion Opportunity (2012)
Consumer Wealth and Spending: The $12 Trillion Opportunity (2012)Melih ÖZCANLI
 

Similar to Slides.pdf (14)

R. sudarshan, public sector adaptation to pandemic era uncertainty some lesso...
R. sudarshan, public sector adaptation to pandemic era uncertainty some lesso...R. sudarshan, public sector adaptation to pandemic era uncertainty some lesso...
R. sudarshan, public sector adaptation to pandemic era uncertainty some lesso...
 
Redistribution through Markets
Redistribution through MarketsRedistribution through Markets
Redistribution through Markets
 
Rethink x+humanity+report
Rethink x+humanity+reportRethink x+humanity+report
Rethink x+humanity+report
 
9 principal unlocking the future of capital markets
9 principal unlocking the future of capital markets9 principal unlocking the future of capital markets
9 principal unlocking the future of capital markets
 
Emerging Consumer Survey 2015 (9 Key Countries Emerging Economies: Brazil, Ch...
Emerging Consumer Survey 2015 (9 Key Countries Emerging Economies: Brazil, Ch...Emerging Consumer Survey 2015 (9 Key Countries Emerging Economies: Brazil, Ch...
Emerging Consumer Survey 2015 (9 Key Countries Emerging Economies: Brazil, Ch...
 
emerging-consumer-survey-2015
emerging-consumer-survey-2015emerging-consumer-survey-2015
emerging-consumer-survey-2015
 
slideshare.pptx
slideshare.pptxslideshare.pptx
slideshare.pptx
 
Help Me Write My Essay For Free
Help Me Write My Essay For FreeHelp Me Write My Essay For Free
Help Me Write My Essay For Free
 
Continuing Resolution
Continuing ResolutionContinuing Resolution
Continuing Resolution
 
Future Agenda 20 Insights For 2020 Final
Future Agenda   20 Insights For 2020   FinalFuture Agenda   20 Insights For 2020   Final
Future Agenda 20 Insights For 2020 Final
 
2012 cities-of-opportunity
2012 cities-of-opportunity2012 cities-of-opportunity
2012 cities-of-opportunity
 
UDI-ism
UDI-ismUDI-ism
UDI-ism
 
Regional Economic Blocks, Regional Public Goods and Development
Regional Economic Blocks, Regional Public Goods and DevelopmentRegional Economic Blocks, Regional Public Goods and Development
Regional Economic Blocks, Regional Public Goods and Development
 
Consumer Wealth and Spending: The $12 Trillion Opportunity (2012)
Consumer Wealth and Spending: The $12 Trillion Opportunity (2012)Consumer Wealth and Spending: The $12 Trillion Opportunity (2012)
Consumer Wealth and Spending: The $12 Trillion Opportunity (2012)
 

More from GRAPE

Gender board diversity and firm performance: evidence from European data
Gender board diversity and firm performance: evidence from European dataGender board diversity and firm performance: evidence from European data
Gender board diversity and firm performance: evidence from European dataGRAPE
 
Demographic transition and the rise of wealth inequality
Demographic transition and the rise of wealth inequalityDemographic transition and the rise of wealth inequality
Demographic transition and the rise of wealth inequalityGRAPE
 
(Gender) tone at the top: the effect of board diversity on gender inequality
(Gender) tone at the top: the effect of board diversity on gender inequality(Gender) tone at the top: the effect of board diversity on gender inequality
(Gender) tone at the top: the effect of board diversity on gender inequalityGRAPE
 
Gender board diversity spillovers and the public eye
Gender board diversity spillovers and the public eyeGender board diversity spillovers and the public eye
Gender board diversity spillovers and the public eyeGRAPE
 
Wage Inequality and women's self-employment
Wage Inequality and women's self-employmentWage Inequality and women's self-employment
Wage Inequality and women's self-employmentGRAPE
 
Contracts with Interdependent Preferences (2)
Contracts with Interdependent Preferences (2)Contracts with Interdependent Preferences (2)
Contracts with Interdependent Preferences (2)GRAPE
 
Empathy in risky choices on behalf of others
Empathy in risky choices on behalf of othersEmpathy in risky choices on behalf of others
Empathy in risky choices on behalf of othersGRAPE
 
Contracts with Interdependent Preferences
Contracts with Interdependent PreferencesContracts with Interdependent Preferences
Contracts with Interdependent PreferencesGRAPE
 
Tone at the top: the effects of gender board diversity on gender wage inequal...
Tone at the top: the effects of gender board diversity on gender wage inequal...Tone at the top: the effects of gender board diversity on gender wage inequal...
Tone at the top: the effects of gender board diversity on gender wage inequal...GRAPE
 
Gender board diversity spillovers and the public eye
Gender board diversity spillovers and the public eyeGender board diversity spillovers and the public eye
Gender board diversity spillovers and the public eyeGRAPE
 
The European Unemployment Puzzle: implications from population aging
The European Unemployment Puzzle: implications from population agingThe European Unemployment Puzzle: implications from population aging
The European Unemployment Puzzle: implications from population agingGRAPE
 
ENTIME_GEM___GAP.pdf
ENTIME_GEM___GAP.pdfENTIME_GEM___GAP.pdf
ENTIME_GEM___GAP.pdfGRAPE
 
POSTER_EARHART.pdf
POSTER_EARHART.pdfPOSTER_EARHART.pdf
POSTER_EARHART.pdfGRAPE
 
Boston_College Slides.pdf
Boston_College Slides.pdfBoston_College Slides.pdf
Boston_College Slides.pdfGRAPE
 
Presentation_Yale.pdf
Presentation_Yale.pdfPresentation_Yale.pdf
Presentation_Yale.pdfGRAPE
 
Presentation_Columbia.pdf
Presentation_Columbia.pdfPresentation_Columbia.pdf
Presentation_Columbia.pdfGRAPE
 
Presentation.pdf
Presentation.pdfPresentation.pdf
Presentation.pdfGRAPE
 
Presentation.pdf
Presentation.pdfPresentation.pdf
Presentation.pdfGRAPE
 
Presentation.pdf
Presentation.pdfPresentation.pdf
Presentation.pdfGRAPE
 
DDKT-Munich.pdf
DDKT-Munich.pdfDDKT-Munich.pdf
DDKT-Munich.pdfGRAPE
 

More from GRAPE (20)

Gender board diversity and firm performance: evidence from European data
Gender board diversity and firm performance: evidence from European dataGender board diversity and firm performance: evidence from European data
Gender board diversity and firm performance: evidence from European data
 
Demographic transition and the rise of wealth inequality
Demographic transition and the rise of wealth inequalityDemographic transition and the rise of wealth inequality
Demographic transition and the rise of wealth inequality
 
(Gender) tone at the top: the effect of board diversity on gender inequality
(Gender) tone at the top: the effect of board diversity on gender inequality(Gender) tone at the top: the effect of board diversity on gender inequality
(Gender) tone at the top: the effect of board diversity on gender inequality
 
Gender board diversity spillovers and the public eye
Gender board diversity spillovers and the public eyeGender board diversity spillovers and the public eye
Gender board diversity spillovers and the public eye
 
Wage Inequality and women's self-employment
Wage Inequality and women's self-employmentWage Inequality and women's self-employment
Wage Inequality and women's self-employment
 
Contracts with Interdependent Preferences (2)
Contracts with Interdependent Preferences (2)Contracts with Interdependent Preferences (2)
Contracts with Interdependent Preferences (2)
 
Empathy in risky choices on behalf of others
Empathy in risky choices on behalf of othersEmpathy in risky choices on behalf of others
Empathy in risky choices on behalf of others
 
Contracts with Interdependent Preferences
Contracts with Interdependent PreferencesContracts with Interdependent Preferences
Contracts with Interdependent Preferences
 
Tone at the top: the effects of gender board diversity on gender wage inequal...
Tone at the top: the effects of gender board diversity on gender wage inequal...Tone at the top: the effects of gender board diversity on gender wage inequal...
Tone at the top: the effects of gender board diversity on gender wage inequal...
 
Gender board diversity spillovers and the public eye
Gender board diversity spillovers and the public eyeGender board diversity spillovers and the public eye
Gender board diversity spillovers and the public eye
 
The European Unemployment Puzzle: implications from population aging
The European Unemployment Puzzle: implications from population agingThe European Unemployment Puzzle: implications from population aging
The European Unemployment Puzzle: implications from population aging
 
ENTIME_GEM___GAP.pdf
ENTIME_GEM___GAP.pdfENTIME_GEM___GAP.pdf
ENTIME_GEM___GAP.pdf
 
POSTER_EARHART.pdf
POSTER_EARHART.pdfPOSTER_EARHART.pdf
POSTER_EARHART.pdf
 
Boston_College Slides.pdf
Boston_College Slides.pdfBoston_College Slides.pdf
Boston_College Slides.pdf
 
Presentation_Yale.pdf
Presentation_Yale.pdfPresentation_Yale.pdf
Presentation_Yale.pdf
 
Presentation_Columbia.pdf
Presentation_Columbia.pdfPresentation_Columbia.pdf
Presentation_Columbia.pdf
 
Presentation.pdf
Presentation.pdfPresentation.pdf
Presentation.pdf
 
Presentation.pdf
Presentation.pdfPresentation.pdf
Presentation.pdf
 
Presentation.pdf
Presentation.pdfPresentation.pdf
Presentation.pdf
 
DDKT-Munich.pdf
DDKT-Munich.pdfDDKT-Munich.pdf
DDKT-Munich.pdf
 

Recently uploaded

Q3 2024 Earnings Conference Call and Webcast Slides
Q3 2024 Earnings Conference Call and Webcast SlidesQ3 2024 Earnings Conference Call and Webcast Slides
Q3 2024 Earnings Conference Call and Webcast SlidesMarketing847413
 
How Automation is Driving Efficiency Through the Last Mile of Reporting
How Automation is Driving Efficiency Through the Last Mile of ReportingHow Automation is Driving Efficiency Through the Last Mile of Reporting
How Automation is Driving Efficiency Through the Last Mile of ReportingAggregage
 
Bladex Earnings Call Presentation 1Q2024
Bladex Earnings Call Presentation 1Q2024Bladex Earnings Call Presentation 1Q2024
Bladex Earnings Call Presentation 1Q2024Bladex
 
Stock Market Brief Deck for 4/24/24 .pdf
Stock Market Brief Deck for 4/24/24 .pdfStock Market Brief Deck for 4/24/24 .pdf
Stock Market Brief Deck for 4/24/24 .pdfMichael Silva
 
Independent Lucknow Call Girls 8923113531WhatsApp Lucknow Call Girls make you...
Independent Lucknow Call Girls 8923113531WhatsApp Lucknow Call Girls make you...Independent Lucknow Call Girls 8923113531WhatsApp Lucknow Call Girls make you...
Independent Lucknow Call Girls 8923113531WhatsApp Lucknow Call Girls make you...makika9823
 
Financial Leverage Definition, Advantages, and Disadvantages
Financial Leverage Definition, Advantages, and DisadvantagesFinancial Leverage Definition, Advantages, and Disadvantages
Financial Leverage Definition, Advantages, and Disadvantagesjayjaymabutot13
 
20240417-Calibre-April-2024-Investor-Presentation.pdf
20240417-Calibre-April-2024-Investor-Presentation.pdf20240417-Calibre-April-2024-Investor-Presentation.pdf
20240417-Calibre-April-2024-Investor-Presentation.pdfAdnet Communications
 
Tenets of Physiocracy History of Economic
Tenets of Physiocracy History of EconomicTenets of Physiocracy History of Economic
Tenets of Physiocracy History of Economiccinemoviesu
 
Attachment Of Assets......................
Attachment Of Assets......................Attachment Of Assets......................
Attachment Of Assets......................AmanBajaj36
 
原版1:1复刻堪萨斯大学毕业证KU毕业证留信学历认证
原版1:1复刻堪萨斯大学毕业证KU毕业证留信学历认证原版1:1复刻堪萨斯大学毕业证KU毕业证留信学历认证
原版1:1复刻堪萨斯大学毕业证KU毕业证留信学历认证jdkhjh
 
Bladex 1Q24 Earning Results Presentation
Bladex 1Q24 Earning Results PresentationBladex 1Q24 Earning Results Presentation
Bladex 1Q24 Earning Results PresentationBladex
 
Vip B Aizawl Call Girls #9907093804 Contact Number Escorts Service Aizawl
Vip B Aizawl Call Girls #9907093804 Contact Number Escorts Service AizawlVip B Aizawl Call Girls #9907093804 Contact Number Escorts Service Aizawl
Vip B Aizawl Call Girls #9907093804 Contact Number Escorts Service Aizawlmakika9823
 
Authentic No 1 Amil Baba In Pakistan Authentic No 1 Amil Baba In Karachi No 1...
Authentic No 1 Amil Baba In Pakistan Authentic No 1 Amil Baba In Karachi No 1...Authentic No 1 Amil Baba In Pakistan Authentic No 1 Amil Baba In Karachi No 1...
Authentic No 1 Amil Baba In Pakistan Authentic No 1 Amil Baba In Karachi No 1...First NO1 World Amil baba in Faisalabad
 
Russian Call Girls In Gtb Nagar (Delhi) 9711199012 💋✔💕😘 Naughty Call Girls Se...
Russian Call Girls In Gtb Nagar (Delhi) 9711199012 💋✔💕😘 Naughty Call Girls Se...Russian Call Girls In Gtb Nagar (Delhi) 9711199012 💋✔💕😘 Naughty Call Girls Se...
Russian Call Girls In Gtb Nagar (Delhi) 9711199012 💋✔💕😘 Naughty Call Girls Se...shivangimorya083
 
Call Girls In Yusuf Sarai Women Seeking Men 9654467111
Call Girls In Yusuf Sarai Women Seeking Men 9654467111Call Girls In Yusuf Sarai Women Seeking Men 9654467111
Call Girls In Yusuf Sarai Women Seeking Men 9654467111Sapana Sha
 
Call Girls Near Golden Tulip Essential Hotel, New Delhi 9873777170
Call Girls Near Golden Tulip Essential Hotel, New Delhi 9873777170Call Girls Near Golden Tulip Essential Hotel, New Delhi 9873777170
Call Girls Near Golden Tulip Essential Hotel, New Delhi 9873777170Sonam Pathan
 
(办理原版一样)QUT毕业证昆士兰科技大学毕业证学位证留信学历认证成绩单补办
(办理原版一样)QUT毕业证昆士兰科技大学毕业证学位证留信学历认证成绩单补办(办理原版一样)QUT毕业证昆士兰科技大学毕业证学位证留信学历认证成绩单补办
(办理原版一样)QUT毕业证昆士兰科技大学毕业证学位证留信学历认证成绩单补办fqiuho152
 
letter-from-the-chair-to-the-fca-relating-to-british-steel-pensions-scheme-15...
letter-from-the-chair-to-the-fca-relating-to-british-steel-pensions-scheme-15...letter-from-the-chair-to-the-fca-relating-to-british-steel-pensions-scheme-15...
letter-from-the-chair-to-the-fca-relating-to-british-steel-pensions-scheme-15...Henry Tapper
 
原版1:1复刻温哥华岛大学毕业证Vancouver毕业证留信学历认证
原版1:1复刻温哥华岛大学毕业证Vancouver毕业证留信学历认证原版1:1复刻温哥华岛大学毕业证Vancouver毕业证留信学历认证
原版1:1复刻温哥华岛大学毕业证Vancouver毕业证留信学历认证rjrjkk
 

Recently uploaded (20)

Q3 2024 Earnings Conference Call and Webcast Slides
Q3 2024 Earnings Conference Call and Webcast SlidesQ3 2024 Earnings Conference Call and Webcast Slides
Q3 2024 Earnings Conference Call and Webcast Slides
 
How Automation is Driving Efficiency Through the Last Mile of Reporting
How Automation is Driving Efficiency Through the Last Mile of ReportingHow Automation is Driving Efficiency Through the Last Mile of Reporting
How Automation is Driving Efficiency Through the Last Mile of Reporting
 
Bladex Earnings Call Presentation 1Q2024
Bladex Earnings Call Presentation 1Q2024Bladex Earnings Call Presentation 1Q2024
Bladex Earnings Call Presentation 1Q2024
 
Stock Market Brief Deck for 4/24/24 .pdf
Stock Market Brief Deck for 4/24/24 .pdfStock Market Brief Deck for 4/24/24 .pdf
Stock Market Brief Deck for 4/24/24 .pdf
 
Independent Lucknow Call Girls 8923113531WhatsApp Lucknow Call Girls make you...
Independent Lucknow Call Girls 8923113531WhatsApp Lucknow Call Girls make you...Independent Lucknow Call Girls 8923113531WhatsApp Lucknow Call Girls make you...
Independent Lucknow Call Girls 8923113531WhatsApp Lucknow Call Girls make you...
 
Financial Leverage Definition, Advantages, and Disadvantages
Financial Leverage Definition, Advantages, and DisadvantagesFinancial Leverage Definition, Advantages, and Disadvantages
Financial Leverage Definition, Advantages, and Disadvantages
 
20240417-Calibre-April-2024-Investor-Presentation.pdf
20240417-Calibre-April-2024-Investor-Presentation.pdf20240417-Calibre-April-2024-Investor-Presentation.pdf
20240417-Calibre-April-2024-Investor-Presentation.pdf
 
Tenets of Physiocracy History of Economic
Tenets of Physiocracy History of EconomicTenets of Physiocracy History of Economic
Tenets of Physiocracy History of Economic
 
Attachment Of Assets......................
Attachment Of Assets......................Attachment Of Assets......................
Attachment Of Assets......................
 
原版1:1复刻堪萨斯大学毕业证KU毕业证留信学历认证
原版1:1复刻堪萨斯大学毕业证KU毕业证留信学历认证原版1:1复刻堪萨斯大学毕业证KU毕业证留信学历认证
原版1:1复刻堪萨斯大学毕业证KU毕业证留信学历认证
 
Bladex 1Q24 Earning Results Presentation
Bladex 1Q24 Earning Results PresentationBladex 1Q24 Earning Results Presentation
Bladex 1Q24 Earning Results Presentation
 
Vip B Aizawl Call Girls #9907093804 Contact Number Escorts Service Aizawl
Vip B Aizawl Call Girls #9907093804 Contact Number Escorts Service AizawlVip B Aizawl Call Girls #9907093804 Contact Number Escorts Service Aizawl
Vip B Aizawl Call Girls #9907093804 Contact Number Escorts Service Aizawl
 
Authentic No 1 Amil Baba In Pakistan Authentic No 1 Amil Baba In Karachi No 1...
Authentic No 1 Amil Baba In Pakistan Authentic No 1 Amil Baba In Karachi No 1...Authentic No 1 Amil Baba In Pakistan Authentic No 1 Amil Baba In Karachi No 1...
Authentic No 1 Amil Baba In Pakistan Authentic No 1 Amil Baba In Karachi No 1...
 
Russian Call Girls In Gtb Nagar (Delhi) 9711199012 💋✔💕😘 Naughty Call Girls Se...
Russian Call Girls In Gtb Nagar (Delhi) 9711199012 💋✔💕😘 Naughty Call Girls Se...Russian Call Girls In Gtb Nagar (Delhi) 9711199012 💋✔💕😘 Naughty Call Girls Se...
Russian Call Girls In Gtb Nagar (Delhi) 9711199012 💋✔💕😘 Naughty Call Girls Se...
 
Call Girls In Yusuf Sarai Women Seeking Men 9654467111
Call Girls In Yusuf Sarai Women Seeking Men 9654467111Call Girls In Yusuf Sarai Women Seeking Men 9654467111
Call Girls In Yusuf Sarai Women Seeking Men 9654467111
 
Call Girls Near Golden Tulip Essential Hotel, New Delhi 9873777170
Call Girls Near Golden Tulip Essential Hotel, New Delhi 9873777170Call Girls Near Golden Tulip Essential Hotel, New Delhi 9873777170
Call Girls Near Golden Tulip Essential Hotel, New Delhi 9873777170
 
(办理原版一样)QUT毕业证昆士兰科技大学毕业证学位证留信学历认证成绩单补办
(办理原版一样)QUT毕业证昆士兰科技大学毕业证学位证留信学历认证成绩单补办(办理原版一样)QUT毕业证昆士兰科技大学毕业证学位证留信学历认证成绩单补办
(办理原版一样)QUT毕业证昆士兰科技大学毕业证学位证留信学历认证成绩单补办
 
letter-from-the-chair-to-the-fca-relating-to-british-steel-pensions-scheme-15...
letter-from-the-chair-to-the-fca-relating-to-british-steel-pensions-scheme-15...letter-from-the-chair-to-the-fca-relating-to-british-steel-pensions-scheme-15...
letter-from-the-chair-to-the-fca-relating-to-british-steel-pensions-scheme-15...
 
原版1:1复刻温哥华岛大学毕业证Vancouver毕业证留信学历认证
原版1:1复刻温哥华岛大学毕业证Vancouver毕业证留信学历认证原版1:1复刻温哥华岛大学毕业证Vancouver毕业证留信学历认证
原版1:1复刻温哥华岛大学毕业证Vancouver毕业证留信学历认证
 
Monthly Economic Monitoring of Ukraine No 231, April 2024
Monthly Economic Monitoring of Ukraine No 231, April 2024Monthly Economic Monitoring of Ukraine No 231, April 2024
Monthly Economic Monitoring of Ukraine No 231, April 2024
 

Slides.pdf

  • 1. Ordeals and Redistribution Piotr Dworczak* (Northwestern University & GRAPE) October 23, 2023 Based on research with Frank Yang and Mohammad Akbarpour Normative Economics & Economic Policy webinar *Co-funded by the European Union (ERC, IMD-101040122). Views and opinions expressed are those of the authors only and do not necessarily reflect those of the European Union or the European Research Council.
  • 2. Inequality-aware Market Design Inequality-aware Market Design (IMD): How to design individual markets in the presence of inequality?
  • 3. Inequality-aware Market Design Inequality-aware Market Design (IMD): How to design individual markets in the presence of inequality? “Redistribution through markets” is very common:
  • 4. Inequality-aware Market Design Inequality-aware Market Design (IMD): How to design individual markets in the presence of inequality? “Redistribution through markets” is very common: rent control, public housing, food stamps, free road access, Covid-19 vaccines, legal services, in-kind provision of food items, controlling the prices of energy, ...
  • 5. Inequality-aware Market Design Inequality-aware Market Design (IMD): How to design individual markets in the presence of inequality? “Redistribution through markets” is very common: rent control, public housing, food stamps, free road access, Covid-19 vaccines, legal services, in-kind provision of food items, controlling the prices of energy, ... Given some redistributive preferences (welfare weights), what is the best way to structure such policies under imperfect information of the planner?
  • 6. Inequality-aware Market Design Inequality-aware Market Design (IMD): How to design individual markets in the presence of inequality? “Redistribution through markets” is very common: rent control, public housing, food stamps, free road access, Covid-19 vaccines, legal services, in-kind provision of food items, controlling the prices of energy, ... Given some redistributive preferences (welfare weights), what is the best way to structure such policies under imperfect information of the planner? D r ⃝ Kominers r ⃝ Akbarpour (2021), A r ⃝ D r ⃝ K (2023), A r ⃝ Budish r ⃝ D r ⃝ K (2023), Tokarski r ⃝ K r ⃝ A r ⃝ D (2023)
  • 7. Inequality-aware Market Design Inequality-aware Market Design (IMD): How to design individual markets in the presence of inequality? “Redistribution through markets” is very common: rent control, public housing, food stamps, free road access, Covid-19 vaccines, legal services, in-kind provision of food items, controlling the prices of energy, ... Given some redistributive preferences (welfare weights), what is the best way to structure such policies under imperfect information of the planner? D r ⃝ Kominers r ⃝ Akbarpour (2021), A r ⃝ D r ⃝ K (2023), A r ⃝ Budish r ⃝ D r ⃝ K (2023), Tokarski r ⃝ K r ⃝ A r ⃝ D (2023) Ongoing effort: Interaction of IMD with optimal taxation
  • 8. Inequality-aware Market Design Inequality-aware Market Design (IMD): How to design individual markets in the presence of inequality? “Redistribution through markets” is very common: rent control, public housing, food stamps, free road access, Covid-19 vaccines, legal services, in-kind provision of food items, controlling the prices of energy, ... Given some redistributive preferences (welfare weights), what is the best way to structure such policies under imperfect information of the planner? D r ⃝ Kominers r ⃝ Akbarpour (2021), A r ⃝ D r ⃝ K (2023), A r ⃝ Budish r ⃝ D r ⃝ K (2023), Tokarski r ⃝ K r ⃝ A r ⃝ D (2023) Ongoing effort: Interaction of IMD with optimal taxation Doligalski, D, Krysta, and Tokarski (2023)
  • 9. Ordeals and Redistribution Today, we will focus on a particular distortion—ordeals.
  • 10. Ordeals and Redistribution Today, we will focus on a particular distortion—ordeals. Ordeal: activity that is costly for the agent performing it but does not directly benefit anyone. Examples:
  • 11. Ordeals and Redistribution Today, we will focus on a particular distortion—ordeals. Ordeal: activity that is costly for the agent performing it but does not directly benefit anyone. Examples: Waiting time Travel distance Filling out forms ...
  • 12. Ordeals and Redistribution Today, we will focus on a particular distortion—ordeals. Ordeal: activity that is costly for the agent performing it but does not directly benefit anyone. Examples: Waiting time Deshpande Li (2019), Rose (2021), Zeckhauser (2021) Travel distance Alatas et al. (2016), Hernandez Seira (2022) Filling out forms Deshpande Li (2019), Finkelstein Notowidigdo (2019) ...
  • 13. Ordeals and Redistribution Today, we will focus on a particular distortion—ordeals. Ordeal: activity that is costly for the agent performing it but does not directly benefit anyone. Examples: Waiting time Deshpande Li (2019), Rose (2021), Zeckhauser (2021) Travel distance Alatas et al. (2016), Hernandez Seira (2022) Filling out forms Deshpande Li (2019), Finkelstein Notowidigdo (2019) ... Nichols and Zeckhauser (1982): Ordeals as costly screening devices.
  • 14. Ordeals and Redistribution Today, we will focus on a particular distortion—ordeals. Ordeal: activity that is costly for the agent performing it but does not directly benefit anyone. Examples: Waiting time Deshpande Li (2019), Rose (2021), Zeckhauser (2021) Travel distance Alatas et al. (2016), Hernandez Seira (2022) Filling out forms Deshpande Li (2019), Finkelstein Notowidigdo (2019) ... Nichols and Zeckhauser (1982): Ordeals as costly screening devices. Welfare properties of ordeals are not very well understood.
  • 15. Ordeals and Redistribution Ordeals are particularly useful when allocating money.
  • 16. Ordeals and Redistribution Ordeals are particularly useful when allocating money. Governments often engage in direct in-cash redistribution.
  • 17. Ordeals and Redistribution Ordeals are particularly useful when allocating money. Governments often engage in direct in-cash redistribution. Of course, governments use verifiable information to target.
  • 18. Ordeals and Redistribution Ordeals are particularly useful when allocating money. Governments often engage in direct in-cash redistribution. Of course, governments use verifiable information to target. Should we also screen for unobserved characteristics?
  • 19. Ordeals and Redistribution Ordeals are particularly useful when allocating money. Governments often engage in direct in-cash redistribution. Of course, governments use verifiable information to target. Should we also screen for unobserved characteristics? Two examples for contrast:
  • 20. Ordeals and Redistribution Ordeals are particularly useful when allocating money. Governments often engage in direct in-cash redistribution. Of course, governments use verifiable information to target. Should we also screen for unobserved characteristics? Two examples for contrast: Direct cash subsidies in the US in Covid-19 pandemic;
  • 21. Ordeals and Redistribution Ordeals are particularly useful when allocating money. Governments often engage in direct in-cash redistribution. Of course, governments use verifiable information to target. Should we also screen for unobserved characteristics? Two examples for contrast: Direct cash subsidies in the US in Covid-19 pandemic; Indonesia’s Conditional Cash Transfer Program.
  • 22. Ordeals and Redistribution Ordeals are particularly useful when allocating money. Governments often engage in direct in-cash redistribution. Of course, governments use verifiable information to target. Should we also screen for unobserved characteristics? Two examples for contrast: Direct cash subsidies in the US in Covid-19 pandemic; Indonesia’s Conditional Cash Transfer Program. Should we use an ordeal?
  • 23. Ordeals and Redistribution Ordeals are particularly useful when allocating money. Governments often engage in direct in-cash redistribution. Of course, governments use verifiable information to target. Should we also screen for unobserved characteristics? Two examples for contrast: Direct cash subsidies in the US in Covid-19 pandemic; Indonesia’s Conditional Cash Transfer Program. Should we use an ordeal? “Equity-efficiency trade-off in quasi-linear environments”
  • 24. Ordeals and Redistribution Ordeals are particularly useful when allocating money. Governments often engage in direct in-cash redistribution. Of course, governments use verifiable information to target. Should we also screen for unobserved characteristics? Two examples for contrast: Direct cash subsidies in the US in Covid-19 pandemic; Indonesia’s Conditional Cash Transfer Program. Should we use an ordeal? “Equity-efficiency trade-off in quasi-linear environments” If yes, which ordeal to use?
  • 25. Ordeals and Redistribution Ordeals are particularly useful when allocating money. Governments often engage in direct in-cash redistribution. Of course, governments use verifiable information to target. Should we also screen for unobserved characteristics? Two examples for contrast: Direct cash subsidies in the US in Covid-19 pandemic; Indonesia’s Conditional Cash Transfer Program. Should we use an ordeal? “Equity-efficiency trade-off in quasi-linear environments” If yes, which ordeal to use? “Comparison of Screening Devices” (with F. Yang and M. Akbarpour)
  • 26. Note on literature It is well known that ordeals can improve targeting: McAfee McMillan (1992), Hartline Rouchgarden (2008), Condorelli (2012), Chakravarty Kaplan (2013), Yang (2023), ... Most of the theory work focused on efficiency as design goal (allocation of goods other than money!) Moreover, all of these papers fix a screening device. Classical references: Weitzman (1977), Nichols Zeckhauser (1982), Besley Coate (1992), Saez and Stantcheva (2016), ... Other papers on IMD: Condorelli (2013), Z. Kang (2020), M. Kang and Zheng (2020), Pai and Strack (2022), ...
  • 27. Paper #1 “Equity-efficiency trade-off in quasi-linear environments”
  • 28. What I do I study a “pure” redistribution problem: How to allocate cash to agents differing in their (privately-observed) marginal values for money (welfare weights).
  • 29. What I do I study a “pure” redistribution problem: How to allocate cash to agents differing in their (privately-observed) marginal values for money (welfare weights). Absent additional information, the only incentive-compatible mechanism is a lump-sum transfer.
  • 30. What I do I study a “pure” redistribution problem: How to allocate cash to agents differing in their (privately-observed) marginal values for money (welfare weights). Absent additional information, the only incentive-compatible mechanism is a lump-sum transfer. But what if the designer can ask agents to burn utility (an “ordeal mechanism”)?
  • 31. What I do I study a “pure” redistribution problem: How to allocate cash to agents differing in their (privately-observed) marginal values for money (welfare weights). Absent additional information, the only incentive-compatible mechanism is a lump-sum transfer. But what if the designer can ask agents to burn utility (an “ordeal mechanism”)? Trade-off: Better targeting but lower efficiency.
  • 32. What I do I study a “pure” redistribution problem: How to allocate cash to agents differing in their (privately-observed) marginal values for money (welfare weights). Absent additional information, the only incentive-compatible mechanism is a lump-sum transfer. But what if the designer can ask agents to burn utility (an “ordeal mechanism”)? Trade-off: Better targeting but lower efficiency. Main result: A condition for optimality of using an ordeal.
  • 33. What I do I study a “pure” redistribution problem: How to allocate cash to agents differing in their (privately-observed) marginal values for money (welfare weights). Absent additional information, the only incentive-compatible mechanism is a lump-sum transfer. But what if the designer can ask agents to burn utility (an “ordeal mechanism”)? Trade-off: Better targeting but lower efficiency. Main result: A condition for optimality of using an ordeal. Simple intuition.
  • 35. Model Designer has a budget B of money that she allocates to a unit mass of agents.
  • 36. Model Designer has a budget B of money that she allocates to a unit mass of agents. Each agent has a “marginal value for money” v that is the agent’s private information (this is just a welfare weight, as in Saez and Stantcheva, 2016)
  • 37. Model Designer has a budget B of money that she allocates to a unit mass of agents. Each agent has a “marginal value for money” v that is the agent’s private information (this is just a welfare weight, as in Saez and Stantcheva, 2016) The designer knows the distribution and maximizes total value.
  • 38. Model Designer has a budget B of money that she allocates to a unit mass of agents. Each agent has a “marginal value for money” v that is the agent’s private information (this is just a welfare weight, as in Saez and Stantcheva, 2016) The designer knows the distribution and maximizes total value. Wlog, designer has no additional information.
  • 39. Model Designer has a budget B of money that she allocates to a unit mass of agents. Each agent has a “marginal value for money” v that is the agent’s private information (this is just a welfare weight, as in Saez and Stantcheva, 2016) The designer knows the distribution and maximizes total value. Wlog, designer has no additional information. The value of giving a lump-sum transfer is simply E[v] B.
  • 40. Model Designer has a budget B of money that she allocates to a unit mass of agents. Each agent has a “marginal value for money” v that is the agent’s private information (this is just a welfare weight, as in Saez and Stantcheva, 2016) The designer knows the distribution and maximizes total value. Wlog, designer has no additional information. The value of giving a lump-sum transfer is simply E[v] B. I normalize E[v] = 1 (the “marginal value of public funds”).
  • 41. Model Suppose the designer can ask agents to “burn utility”: Complete a task that is publicly observable, costly to the agent, and socially wasteful (an “ordeal”).
  • 42. Model Suppose the designer can ask agents to “burn utility”: Complete a task that is publicly observable, costly to the agent, and socially wasteful (an “ordeal”). The designer can choose a difficulty level y 2 [0; 1].
  • 43. Model Suppose the designer can ask agents to “burn utility”: Complete a task that is publicly observable, costly to the agent, and socially wasteful (an “ordeal”). The designer can choose a difficulty level y 2 [0; 1]. Each agent has a privately-observed cost c.
  • 44. Model Suppose the designer can ask agents to “burn utility”: Complete a task that is publicly observable, costly to the agent, and socially wasteful (an “ordeal”). The designer can choose a difficulty level y 2 [0; 1]. Each agent has a privately-observed cost c. Utility of each agent is quasi-linear: cy + vt; when completing ordeal y and receiving a transfer t.
  • 45. Model Suppose the designer can ask agents to “burn utility”: Complete a task that is publicly observable, costly to the agent, and socially wasteful (an “ordeal”). The designer can choose a difficulty level y 2 [0; 1]. Each agent has a privately-observed cost c. Utility of each agent is quasi-linear: cy + vt; when completing ordeal y and receiving a transfer t. Cost c measured in “social-utility units;” let k c=v be the cost measured in money— only k matters for agents’ choices.
  • 46. Model Suppose the designer can ask agents to “burn utility”: Complete a task that is publicly observable, costly to the agent, and socially wasteful (an “ordeal”). The designer can choose a difficulty level y 2 [0; 1]. Each agent has a privately-observed cost c. Utility of each agent is quasi-linear: cy + vt; when completing ordeal y and receiving a transfer t. Cost c measured in “social-utility units;” let k c=v be the cost measured in money— only k matters for agents’ choices. Assume k F with C1 density f on [k; k̄] with k = 0, f(k) 0.
  • 47. Model The designer now maximizes E[ cy(k) + vt(k)] subject to budget constraint and incentive-compatibility (self-selection based on k).
  • 48. Model The designer now maximizes E[ cy(k) + vt(k)] subject to budget constraint and incentive-compatibility (self-selection based on k). Note: Any positive level of y is a pure social waste.
  • 49. Model The designer now maximizes E[ cy(k) + vt(k)] subject to budget constraint and incentive-compatibility (self-selection based on k). Note: Any positive level of y is a pure social waste. If no redistributive preferences (all v = 1), then trivially lump-sum payment is optimal.
  • 50. Model The designer now maximizes E[ cy(k) + vt(k)] subject to budget constraint and incentive-compatibility (self-selection based on k). Note: Any positive level of y is a pure social waste. If no redistributive preferences (all v = 1), then trivially lump-sum payment is optimal. But in general, there is an equity-efficiency trade-off.
  • 52. Analysis Suppose that the designer offers an additional payment t0 for an ordeal y0 0.
  • 53. Analysis Suppose that the designer offers an additional payment t0 for an ordeal y0 0. Agents with k t0=y0 accept.
  • 54. Analysis Suppose that the designer offers an additional payment t0 for an ordeal y0 0. Agents with k t0=y0 accept. Let E h vjc v = k i be the conditional expectation of v conditional on the relative cost being equal to k (assumed continuous).
  • 55. Analysis Suppose that the designer offers an additional payment t0 for an ordeal y0 0. Agents with k t0=y0 accept. Let E h vjc v = k i be the conditional expectation of v conditional on the relative cost being equal to k (assumed continuous). E[vjk] measures targeting effectiveness.
  • 56. Analysis Suppose that the designer offers an additional payment t0 for an ordeal y0 0. Agents with k t0=y0 accept. Let E h vjc v = k i be the conditional expectation of v conditional on the relative cost being equal to k (assumed continuous). E[vjk] measures targeting effectiveness. Designer’s payoff from this “ordeal mechanism:” Z t0=y0 0 E[vjk] (t0 ky0)f(k)dk + (B t0F(t0=y0)):
  • 57. Analysis We want to check whether the ordeal mechanism strictly outperforms the lump-sum transfer for small t0 = y0: Z 0 E[vjk]( k)f(k)dk F():
  • 58. Analysis We want to check whether the ordeal mechanism strictly outperforms the lump-sum transfer for small t0 = y0: Z 0 E[vjk]( k)f(k)dk F(): Enough to prove that the ratio of the RHS to LHS is above 1 in the limit: lim !0 R 0 E[vjk]( k)f(k)dk F() (h) = lim !0 R 0 E[vjk]f(k)dk f() + F() (h) = E[vjk] 2 ; by L’Hôpital’s rule.
  • 59. Analysis We want to check whether the ordeal mechanism strictly outperforms the lump-sum transfer for small t0 = y0: Z 0 E[vjk]( k)f(k)dk F(): Enough to prove that the ratio of the RHS to LHS is above 1 in the limit: lim !0 R 0 E[vjk]( k)f(k)dk F() (h) = lim !0 R 0 E[vjk]f(k)dk f() + F() (h) = E[vjk] 2 ; by L’Hôpital’s rule. So ordeal is better than lump-sum when E[vjk] 2.
  • 60. Analysis Proposition If the expected value for money conditional on the lowest relative cost exceeds the value of public funds by more than a factor of two, i.e., if E[vjk] 2; (?) then the ordeal mechanism strictly outperforms giving a lump-sum transfer for some positive 0.
  • 61. Analysis Proposition If the expected value for money conditional on the lowest relative cost exceeds the value of public funds by more than a factor of two, i.e., if E[vjk] 2; (?) then the ordeal mechanism strictly outperforms giving a lump-sum transfer for some positive 0. Intuitively: Using an ordeal becomes optimal when redistributive preferences are strong enough and targeting effectiveness is high.
  • 62. Why 2? Similar condition arises in papers studying optimal market design under redistributive preferences.
  • 63. Why 2? Similar condition arises in papers studying optimal market design under redistributive preferences. DKA (2021): When designing a goods market, rationing may be optimal when the expected welfare weight conditional on the lowest willingness to pay for the good exceeds the average welfare weight by more than a factor of two.
  • 64. Why 2? Similar condition arises in papers studying optimal market design under redistributive preferences. DKA (2021): When designing a goods market, rationing may be optimal when the expected welfare weight conditional on the lowest willingness to pay for the good exceeds the average welfare weight by more than a factor of two. Versions of this condition (with “2”) keep coming up:
  • 65. Why 2? Similar condition arises in papers studying optimal market design under redistributive preferences. DKA (2021): When designing a goods market, rationing may be optimal when the expected welfare weight conditional on the lowest willingness to pay for the good exceeds the average welfare weight by more than a factor of two. Versions of this condition (with “2”) keep coming up: Z. Kang (2020);
  • 66. Why 2? Similar condition arises in papers studying optimal market design under redistributive preferences. DKA (2021): When designing a goods market, rationing may be optimal when the expected welfare weight conditional on the lowest willingness to pay for the good exceeds the average welfare weight by more than a factor of two. Versions of this condition (with “2”) keep coming up: Z. Kang (2020); M. Kang and Zheng (2020);
  • 67. Why 2? Similar condition arises in papers studying optimal market design under redistributive preferences. DKA (2021): When designing a goods market, rationing may be optimal when the expected welfare weight conditional on the lowest willingness to pay for the good exceeds the average welfare weight by more than a factor of two. Versions of this condition (with “2”) keep coming up: Z. Kang (2020); M. Kang and Zheng (2020); Pai and Strack (2022);
  • 68. Why 2? Similar condition arises in papers studying optimal market design under redistributive preferences. DKA (2021): When designing a goods market, rationing may be optimal when the expected welfare weight conditional on the lowest willingness to pay for the good exceeds the average welfare weight by more than a factor of two. Versions of this condition (with “2”) keep coming up: Z. Kang (2020); M. Kang and Zheng (2020); Pai and Strack (2022); ADK (2023).
  • 69. Why 2? Similar condition arises in papers studying optimal market design under redistributive preferences. DKA (2021): When designing a goods market, rationing may be optimal when the expected welfare weight conditional on the lowest willingness to pay for the good exceeds the average welfare weight by more than a factor of two. Versions of this condition (with “2”) keep coming up: Z. Kang (2020); M. Kang and Zheng (2020); Pai and Strack (2022); ADK (2023). Why “2”?
  • 70. Analysis Proposition If the expected value for money conditional on the lowest relative cost exceeds the value of public funds by more than a factor of two, i.e., if E[vjk] 2; (?) then the ordeal mechanism strictly outperforms giving a lump-sum transfer for some positive 0. High-level intuition: Better targeting requires sacrificing some surplus.
  • 71. Analysis Proposition If the expected value for money conditional on the lowest relative cost exceeds the value of public funds by more than a factor of two, i.e., if E[vjk] 2; (?) then the ordeal mechanism strictly outperforms giving a lump-sum transfer for some positive 0. High-level intuition: Better targeting requires sacrificing some surplus. For every dollar of public funds spent, only 1=2 of the dollar is received by an agent (the other half is “burned” in screening).
  • 72. Analysis Proposition If the expected value for money conditional on the lowest relative cost exceeds the value of public funds by more than a factor of two, i.e., if E[vjk] 2; (?) then the ordeal mechanism strictly outperforms giving a lump-sum transfer for some positive 0. High-level intuition: Better targeting requires sacrificing some surplus. For every dollar of public funds spent, only 1=2 of the dollar is received by an agent (the other half is “burned” in screening). Thus, ordeal is better if the designer values each dollar given to lowest-cost agent at 2 or more.
  • 80. Optimal mechanism Is this intuition robust to choosing the optimal mechanism?
  • 81. Optimal mechanism Is this intuition robust to choosing the optimal mechanism? max y(k)2[0; 1]; t(k)0 Z k̄ k E[vjk]( ky(k) + t(k))dF(k); (OBJ) ky(k) + t(k) ky(k0) + t(k0); 8k; k0; (IC) ky(k) + t(k) 0; 8k; (IR) Z k̄ k t(k)dF(k) = B: (B)
  • 82. Optimal mechanism Proposition The optimal mechanism uses an ordeal (y is strictly positive for some agents) if and only if E[V(k)jk k0] 0 for some k0; (??) where V(k) = E h vjc v k i 1 F(k) f(k) k: (V)
  • 83. Optimal mechanism Proposition The optimal mechanism uses an ordeal (y is strictly positive for some agents) if and only if E[V(k)jk k0] 0 for some k0; (??) where V(k) = E h vjc v k i 1 F(k) f(k) k: (V) Condition (?) implies that V(k) 0 for small enough k; hence, condition (?) implies condition (??).
  • 84. Optimal mechanism Proposition The optimal mechanism uses an ordeal (y is strictly positive for some agents) if and only if E[V(k)jk k0] 0 for some k0; (??) where V(k) = E h vjc v k i 1 F(k) f(k) k: (V) Condition (?) implies that V(k) 0 for small enough k; hence, condition (?) implies condition (??). Conversely, when V(k) is quasi-concave, condition (??) implies that condition (?) must hold as a weak inequality.
  • 85. Optimal mechanism Proposition (continued) When B is large enough, the optimal mechanism offers a single payment k? for completing the ordeal y = 1, and allocates the remaining budget as a lump-sum payment.
  • 86. Optimal mechanism Proposition (continued) When B is large enough, the optimal mechanism offers a single payment k? for completing the ordeal y = 1, and allocates the remaining budget as a lump-sum payment. Intuition: Because I assumed k = 0, we have V(0) = 0.
  • 87. Optimal mechanism Proposition (continued) When B is large enough, the optimal mechanism offers a single payment k? for completing the ordeal y = 1, and allocates the remaining budget as a lump-sum payment. Intuition: Because I assumed k = 0, we have V(0) = 0. Turns out that condition (?) is equivalent to V0(0) 0.
  • 88. Optimal mechanism Proposition (continued) When B is large enough, the optimal mechanism offers a single payment k? for completing the ordeal y = 1, and allocates the remaining budget as a lump-sum payment. Intuition: Because I assumed k = 0, we have V(0) = 0. Turns out that condition (?) is equivalent to V0(0) 0. This condition is (almost) necessary if V is quasi-concave.
  • 90. Concluding remarks Looked at a simple(st?) equity-efficiency problem.
  • 91. Concluding remarks Looked at a simple(st?) equity-efficiency problem. Condition with factor 2 reflects a fundamental equity-efficiency trade-off in quasi-linear environments.
  • 92. Concluding remarks Looked at a simple(st?) equity-efficiency problem. Condition with factor 2 reflects a fundamental equity-efficiency trade-off in quasi-linear environments. The condition is still sufficient without quasi-linearity in money!
  • 93. Concluding remarks Looked at a simple(st?) equity-efficiency problem. Condition with factor 2 reflects a fundamental equity-efficiency trade-off in quasi-linear environments. The condition is still sufficient without quasi-linearity in money! Importance of the assumption k = 0 ! policy implications.
  • 94. Concluding remarks Looked at a simple(st?) equity-efficiency problem. Condition with factor 2 reflects a fundamental equity-efficiency trade-off in quasi-linear environments. The condition is still sufficient without quasi-linearity in money! Importance of the assumption k = 0 ! policy implications. Results silent about which ordeal to use.
  • 95. Paper #2 “Comparison of Screening Devices” (with Frank Yang and Mohammad Akbarpour)
  • 96. Motivation Many allocations use costly screening devices: Waiting time; Filling out forms; Travel distance ; ... For example: Imposing an ordeal of traveling to a registration site improves targeting in Indonesia’s Conditional Cash Transfer program (Alatas et al. 2016) Level of congestion at Social Security Administration field offices affects targeting of disability programs (Deshpande Li 2019) This paper: What makes one screening device better than another?
  • 98. Illustrative Example Allocate mass 2=3 of money to a unit mass of agents, each receiving 1. Types: p(oor), m(iddle class), r(ich) Welfare weights: v = 3, 1, and 0 kA kB v p 1 2 3 m 1 2 1 r 1 1 0 Screening devices A and B: kA and kB are per-unit-of-difficulty costs.
  • 99. Illustrative Example Allocate mass 2=3 of money to a unit mass of agents, each receiving 1. Types: p(oor), m(iddle class), r(ich) Welfare weights: v = 3, 1, and 0 kA kB v p 1 2 3 m 1 2 1 r 1 1 0 Screening devices A and B: kA and kB are per-unit-of-difficulty costs. Screening device A achieves perfect targeting...
  • 100. Illustrative Example Allocate mass 2=3 of money to a unit mass of agents, each receiving 1. Types: p(oor), m(iddle class), r(ich) Welfare weights: v = 3, 1, and 0 kA kB v p 1 2 3 m 1 2 1 r 1 1 0 Screening devices A and B: kA and kB are per-unit-of-difficulty costs. Screening device A achieves perfect targeting... but screening device B is better than A!
  • 101. Illustrative Example Allocate mass 2=3 of money to a unit mass of agents, each receiving 1. Types: p(oor), m(iddle class), r(ich) Welfare weights: v = 3, 1, and 0 kA kB v p 1 2 3 m 1 2 1 r 1 1 0 Screening devices A and B: kA and kB are per-unit-of-difficulty costs. Screening device A achieves perfect targeting... but screening device B is better than A! Under A, “market-clearing” difficulty = 1 unit. Total welfare = 1 3 (3 (2) + 1 ) = 7 3 Under B, “market-clearing” difficulty = 1 2 unit. Total welfare = 1 3 (3 (1 1 2) + 0 0) = 1 1 2
  • 102. Illustrative Example Allocate mass 2=3 of money to a unit mass of agents, each receiving 1. Types: p(oor), m(iddle class), r(ich) Welfare weights: v = 3, 1, and 0 kA kB v p 1 2 3 m 1 2 1 r 1 1 0 Screening devices A and B: kA and kB are per-unit-of-difficulty costs. Screening device A achieves perfect targeting... but screening device B is better than A! Screening device B is worse at targeting but provides higher rents to agents conditional on allocation. kB has lower correlation with v but it has higher dispersion.
  • 104. Costly Screening—framework A screening device D is a conditional distribution D : v ! ∆(R++):
  • 105. Costly Screening—framework A screening device D is a conditional distribution D : v ! ∆(R++): Interpretation: D(v) is the distribution of per-unit-of-difficulty costs k for agents with welfare weight v.
  • 106. Costly Screening—framework A screening device D is a conditional distribution D : v ! ∆(R++): Interpretation: D(v) is the distribution of per-unit-of-difficulty costs k for agents with welfare weight v. This allows us to vary the screening device while holding fixed designer’s redistributive preferences.
  • 107. Costly Screening—framework A screening device D is a conditional distribution D : v ! ∆(R++): Interpretation: D(v) is the distribution of per-unit-of-difficulty costs k for agents with welfare weight v. This allows us to vary the screening device while holding fixed designer’s redistributive preferences. Given D, denote by F the cumulative distribution function of k.
  • 108. Costly Screening—framework A screening device D is a conditional distribution D : v ! ∆(R++): Interpretation: D(v) is the distribution of per-unit-of-difficulty costs k for agents with welfare weight v. This allows us to vary the screening device while holding fixed designer’s redistributive preferences. Given D, denote by F the cumulative distribution function of k. Screening device identified by the joint distribution of (v; k).
  • 109. Costly Screening—framework A screening device D is a conditional distribution D : v ! ∆(R++): Interpretation: D(v) is the distribution of per-unit-of-difficulty costs k for agents with welfare weight v. This allows us to vary the screening device while holding fixed designer’s redistributive preferences. Given D, denote by F the cumulative distribution function of k. Screening device identified by the joint distribution of (v; k). Normalize the maximal quantity of money received by agent to 1; budget B 2 [0; 1]; no restrictions on difficulty y 0.
  • 110. Costly Screening—framework In the paper: Allocation of goods with heterogeneous quality q 2 [0; 1].
  • 111. Costly Screening—framework In the paper: Allocation of goods with heterogeneous quality q 2 [0; 1]. Each agent has a private value w for the good and welfare weight v.
  • 112. Costly Screening—framework In the paper: Allocation of goods with heterogeneous quality q 2 [0; 1]. Each agent has a private value w for the good and welfare weight v. Screening device D maps (v; w) into distribution of costs k.
  • 113. Costly Screening—framework In the paper: Allocation of goods with heterogeneous quality q 2 [0; 1]. Each agent has a private value w for the good and welfare weight v. Screening device D maps (v; w) into distribution of costs k. Utility is wq ky, contribution to social welfare is v(wq ky).
  • 114. Costly Screening—framework In the paper: Allocation of goods with heterogeneous quality q 2 [0; 1]. Each agent has a private value w for the good and welfare weight v. Screening device D maps (v; w) into distribution of costs k. Utility is wq ky, contribution to social welfare is v(wq ky). Marginal rate of substitution: r = w=k.
  • 115. Costly Screening—framework In the paper: Allocation of goods with heterogeneous quality q 2 [0; 1]. Each agent has a private value w for the good and welfare weight v. Screening device D maps (v; w) into distribution of costs k. Utility is wq ky, contribution to social welfare is v(wq ky). Marginal rate of substitution: r = w=k. All results apply if we replace the distribution of inverse costs 1=k with the distribution of the marginal rate of substitution.
  • 116. Designing an ideal screening device? Allocate supply B of money to agents with welfare weights distributed uniformly: v U[0;1].
  • 117. Designing an ideal screening device? Allocate supply B of money to agents with welfare weights distributed uniformly: v U[0;1]. The following screening device achieves the first best: k = 1fv1 Bg.
  • 118. Designing an ideal screening device? Allocate supply B of money to agents with welfare weights distributed uniformly: v U[0;1]. The following screening device achieves the first best: k = 1fv1 Bg. Not practical: cannot freely design screening devices; sensitive to the available supply level.
  • 119. Comparing Screening Devices Screening device D1 dominates screening device D2 if OPT(D1;B) OPT(D2;B) for every supply level B 2 [0;1], where OPT(D;B) is the social welfare induced by the optimal allocation mechanism given screening device D and budget B.
  • 120. Comparing Screening Devices Screening device D1 dominates screening device D2 if OPT(D1;B) OPT(D2;B) for every supply level B 2 [0;1], where OPT(D;B) is the social welfare induced by the optimal allocation mechanism given screening device D and budget B. Question: When does one screening device dominate another?
  • 121. Comparing Screening Devices Screening device D1 dominates screening device D2 if OPT(D1;B) OPT(D2;B) for every supply level B 2 [0;1], where OPT(D;B) is the social welfare induced by the optimal allocation mechanism given screening device D and budget B. Question: When does one screening device dominate another? Remark: While we focus on optimal mechanisms, our results also hold with “market mechanisms” (demand = supply).
  • 123. Characterization of Dominance For any screening device D, define its welfare index at parameter s: W(D;s) := Z s 0 1 F 1(t) F 1(s) | {z } Rent Provision E h v j k = F 1 (t) i | {z } Targeting Effectiveness dt:
  • 124. Characterization of Dominance For any screening device D, define its welfare index at parameter s: W(D;s) := Z s 0 1 F 1(t) F 1(s) | {z } Rent Provision E h v j k = F 1 (t) i | {z } Targeting Effectiveness dt: Rent provision: utility net of screening costs for an agent whose cost is in the bottom t quantile, given supply s; measured in units of money.
  • 125. Characterization of Dominance For any screening device D, define its welfare index at parameter s: W(D;s) := Z s 0 1 F 1(t) F 1(s) | {z } Rent Provision E h v j k = F 1 (t) i | {z } Targeting Effectiveness dt: Rent provision: utility net of screening costs for an agent whose cost is in the bottom t quantile, given supply s; measured in units of money. Targeting effectiveness: converts monetary units to social welfare units; uses information revealed through agent’s cost k.
  • 126. Characterization of Dominance For any screening device D, define its welfare index at parameter s: W(D;s) := Z s 0 1 F 1(t) F 1(s) | {z } Rent Provision E h v j k = F 1 (t) i | {z } Targeting Effectiveness dt: Theorem 1 For any two screening devices D1 and D2, if W(D1;s) W(D2;s); for all s 2 [0;1]; (?) then screening device D1 dominates screening device D2.
  • 127. Characterization of Dominance For any screening device D, define its welfare index at parameter s: W(D;s) := Z s 0 1 F 1(t) F 1(s) | {z } Rent Provision E h v j k = F 1 (t) i | {z } Targeting Effectiveness dt: Theorem 1 For any two screening devices D1 and D2, if W(D1;s) W(D2;s); for all s 2 [0;1]; (?) then screening device D1 dominates screening device D2. Remark: A weakening of (?) is both necessary and sufficient
  • 128. Math Break: Two Notions of Spread Dispersive order: For two random variables X and Y with CDFs FX and FY , X disp Y if F 1 X (t) F 1 X (s) F 1 Y (t) F 1 Y (s); for all 0 s t 1:
  • 129. Math Break: Two Notions of Spread Dispersive order: For two random variables X and Y with CDFs FX and FY , X disp Y if F 1 X (t) F 1 X (s) F 1 Y (t) F 1 Y (s); for all 0 s t 1: Majorization order: For two functions h1 and h2 on [0;1], h2 maj h1 if Z s 0 h2(t)dt Z s 0 h1(t)dt; for all s 2 [0; 1], with equality at s = 1. If h1;h2 are non-decreasing, then this is the same as h2(U) mps h1(U) ; where mps is mean-preserving spread and U is a uniform random variable.
  • 130. Dispersion and Correlation Let V(t) := E[v j k = F 1(t)] be the posterior mean of v when k is equal to its quantile t. Theorem 2 For any two screening devices D1 and D2, if (i) log(k2) disp log(k1), (ii) V2 maj V1, then screening device D1 dominates screening device D2.
  • 131. Dispersion and Correlation Let V(t) := E[v j k = F 1(t)] be the posterior mean of v when k is equal to its quantile t. Theorem 2 For any two screening devices D1 and D2, if (i) log(k2) disp log(k1), (ii) V2 maj V1, then screening device D1 dominates screening device D2. Condition (i): marginal distribution of k Condition (ii): correlation of v and k
  • 132. Dispersion and Correlation Let V(t) := E[v j k = F 1(t)] be the posterior mean of v when k is equal to its quantile t. Theorem 2 For any two screening devices D1 and D2, if (i) log(k2) disp log(k1), (ii) V2 maj V1, then screening device D1 dominates screening device D2. Condition (i): marginal distribution of k Condition (ii): correlation of v and k
  • 133. Dispersion and Correlation Let V(t) := E[v j k = F 1(t)] be the posterior mean of v when k is equal to its quantile t. Theorem 2 For any two screening devices D1 and D2, if (i) log(k2) disp log(k1), (ii) V2 maj V1, then screening device D1 dominates screening device D2. Condition (i): marginal distribution of k Condition (ii): correlation of v and k Dispersion at log level for k () Rent provision Negative correlation of (v;k) () Targeting effectiveness
  • 135. Limits of Costly Screening Proposition 1 For any 0, there exists a screening device D such that, for any budget B, D achieves welfare that is within of the first-best welfare.
  • 136. Limits of Costly Screening Proposition 1 For any 0, there exists a screening device D such that, for any budget B, D achieves welfare that is within of the first-best welfare. D approximates the first-best robustly for all budget levels!
  • 137. Limits of Costly Screening Proposition 1 For any 0, there exists a screening device D such that, for any budget B, D achieves welfare that is within of the first-best welfare. D approximates the first-best robustly for all budget levels! Proof sketch:
  • 138. Limits of Costly Screening Proposition 1 For any 0, there exists a screening device D such that, for any budget B, D achieves welfare that is within of the first-best welfare. D approximates the first-best robustly for all budget levels! Proof sketch: Perfect targeting: make k a strictly decreasing function of v. Increasingly dispersed: make log(k) increasingly dispersed as decreases.
  • 139. Limits of Costly Screening Proposition 2 For any device D and any 0, there exists D such that: (i) D has better targeting effectiveness than D: V maj V; (ii) For any budget B, D achieves social welfare that is less than under the market-clearing rule.
  • 140. Limits of Costly Screening Proposition 2 For any device D and any 0, there exists D such that: (i) D has better targeting effectiveness than D: V maj V; (ii) For any budget B, D achieves social welfare that is less than under the market-clearing rule. Proof sketch: D can be made to achieve perfect targeting; But if log(k) is increasingly compressed then we have arbitrarily low welfare.
  • 141. Importance of Dispersion Proposition 3 Consider any screening devices D; D1; D2; D3 such that k1 = k ∆; k2 = min(k;∆0); k3 = ∆00k; for some constants ∆;∆0; ∆00 0. Then D1 dominates D; D dominates D2; D is equivalent to D3.
  • 142. Importance of Dispersion Proposition 3 Consider any screening devices D; D1; D2; D3 such that k1 = k ∆; k2 = min(k;∆0); k3 = ∆00k; for some constants ∆;∆0; ∆00 0. Then D1 dominates D; D dominates D2; D is equivalent to D3. Even though both D1; D2; D3 reduce the level of costs, uniformly decreasing costs is welfare-enhancing; allowing delegation of the task is welfare-reducing. multiplying costs by a constant is welfare-neutral.
  • 143. Simple Regression Test Proposition 4 If two screening devices D1 and D2 satisfy log(k2) = log(k1) + ; for some 2 [0;1] and random variable that is independent of (v;k1), then D1 dominates D2.
  • 144. Simple Regression Test Proposition 4 If two screening devices D1 and D2 satisfy log(k2) = log(k1) + ; for some 2 [0;1] and random variable that is independent of (v;k1), then D1 dominates D2. D1 and D2 sort agents the same way up to idiosyncratic shocks: Smaller means less dispersion on the log level;
  • 145. Simple Regression Test Proposition 4 If two screening devices D1 and D2 satisfy log(k2) = log(k1) + ; for some 2 [0;1] and random variable that is independent of (v;k1), then D1 dominates D2. D1 and D2 sort agents the same way up to idiosyncratic shocks: Smaller means less dispersion on the log level; introduces a trade-off between dispersion and targeting;
  • 146. Simple Regression Test Proposition 4 If two screening devices D1 and D2 satisfy log(k2) = log(k1) + ; for some 2 [0;1] and random variable that is independent of (v;k1), then D1 dominates D2. D1 and D2 sort agents the same way up to idiosyncratic shocks: Smaller means less dispersion on the log level; introduces a trade-off between dispersion and targeting; Adding idiosyncratic noise makes screening device worse;
  • 147. Simple Regression Test Proposition 4 If two screening devices D1 and D2 satisfy log(k2) = log(k1) + ; for some 2 [0;1] and random variable that is independent of (v;k1), then D1 dominates D2. D1 and D2 sort agents the same way up to idiosyncratic shocks: Smaller means less dispersion on the log level; introduces a trade-off between dispersion and targeting; Adding idiosyncratic noise makes screening device worse; Intuitively, we want variation in log(k) across (not within) groups of different v.
  • 148. Combining Screening Devices For any two screening devices D1 and D2, either: Bundle two devices: Induce a new device D3 by c3 = c1 + c2; Offer a choice: Induce a new device D3 by c3 = min n c1;c2 o :
  • 149. Combining Screening Devices For any two screening devices D1 and D2, either: Bundle two devices: Induce a new device D3 by c3 = c1 + c2; Offer a choice: Induce a new device D3 by c3 = min n c1;c2 o : Proposition 5 If D1 and D2 satisfy c2 = (c1;), where is independent of (v;c1); 0 d log (c;) d log c 1 for all c, almost surely in ; then D1 dominates D3.
  • 151. Concluding Remarks What makes a costly screening device better than another? Two channels:
  • 152. Concluding Remarks What makes a costly screening device better than another? Two channels: rent provision;
  • 153. Concluding Remarks What makes a costly screening device better than another? Two channels: rent provision; targeting effectiveness.
  • 154. Concluding Remarks What makes a costly screening device better than another? Two channels: rent provision; targeting effectiveness. Characterized by:
  • 155. Concluding Remarks What makes a costly screening device better than another? Two channels: rent provision; targeting effectiveness. Characterized by: dispersion of the distribution of costs,
  • 156. Concluding Remarks What makes a costly screening device better than another? Two channels: rent provision; targeting effectiveness. Characterized by: dispersion of the distribution of costs, correlation of costs and welfare weights.
  • 157. Concluding Remarks What makes a costly screening device better than another? Two channels: rent provision; targeting effectiveness. Characterized by: dispersion of the distribution of costs, correlation of costs and welfare weights. Future directions:
  • 158. Concluding Remarks What makes a costly screening device better than another? Two channels: rent provision; targeting effectiveness. Characterized by: dispersion of the distribution of costs, correlation of costs and welfare weights. Future directions: “Useful” ordeals? (Kleven Kopczuk, 2011, Dréze, 2019)
  • 159. Concluding Remarks What makes a costly screening device better than another? Two channels: rent provision; targeting effectiveness. Characterized by: dispersion of the distribution of costs, correlation of costs and welfare weights. Future directions: “Useful” ordeals? (Kleven Kopczuk, 2011, Dréze, 2019) Ethical ramifications?
  • 160. Concluding Remarks What makes a costly screening device better than another? Two channels: rent provision; targeting effectiveness. Characterized by: dispersion of the distribution of costs, correlation of costs and welfare weights. Future directions: “Useful” ordeals? (Kleven Kopczuk, 2011, Dréze, 2019) Ethical ramifications? Interaction with other tools for redistribution? (Ooghe, 2021)