SlideShare a Scribd company logo
1 of 27
Jobs and Protectionism in the Stimulus
Package
President Obama's spending bill promotes the use of
American goods and labor. Despite foreign and domestic
protests, the language is mainly rhetorical
Members of the Senate and the House hash out differences
between the two versions of the
economic stimulus legislation at the U.S. Capitol on Feb. 11
Chip Somodevilla/Getty Images
By Moira Herbst
The $787 billion spending legislation being signed on Feb. 17
by President Barack Obama is
designed to jolt some life into a moribund economy. Already,
though, provisions to use the
money to "buy American"—whether that means American iron,
steel, or labor—is sparking a
debate about whether such rules in a global economy amount to
protectionism.
Organized labor and small U.S. manufacturers won an
amendment to the stimulus bill to ensure
that more materials used on construction and infrastructure are
made in the U.S. Critics of the H-
1B visa program won tougher rules governing when banks that
are bailed out by the Troubled
Assets Relief Program (TARP) can fill jobs with skilled
immigrants.
The final language drew criticism from abroad, where editorials
and government officials
warned it could run afoul of trade agreements. But both
provisions are less stringent than earlier
versions had been, and neither is likely to have a radical effect
on how stimulus spending takes
shape.
http://www.businessweek.com/bios/Moira_Herbst.htm
Opposition from Exporters
The clearest attempt to wall off foreign companies from U.S.
spending came in a "Buy
American" provision. That rule requires that only U.S. iron,
steel, and other manufactured goods
be used for public buildings and public works funded under the
bill. However, it comes with
several key caveats. For one, the language states that the Buy
American policy must not violate
U.S. obligations under existing international trade agreements.
Nor does the rule apply if
American goods aren't available in sufficient quantities or if
they'll increase the cost of the
overall project by more than 25%. Federal highway, transit, and
airport projects are already
covered by similar Buy American requirements.
The battle over the provision had been contentious. On Feb. 3,
100 business groups and
companies—including the U.S. Chamber of Commerce, General
Electric (GE), Caterpillar
(CAT), and other major construction, defense, and high-tech
companies—wrote a letter to Senate
leaders warning that a far-reaching Buy American rule "will
harm American workers and
companies across the entire U.S. economy, undermine U.S.
global engagement, and result in
mirror-image trade restrictions abroad that would put at risk
huge amounts of American exports."
But advocates of the provision—including the Alliance for
American Manufacturing, a
partnership of manufacturing companies and the United
Steelworkers union—said such rules are
needed to stem the tide of layoffs in the U.S. construction and
manufacturing sectors.
Coalition Claims 'Major Victory'
In negotiations, the Obama Administration sought to reconcile
the opposing sides. White House
spokesman Robert Gibbs told reporters on Feb. 12 that the final
bill achieves this. "I think where
we ended up with the Buy America provision is the right
compromise that respects the Buy
America laws that we've had on our books for many, many years
while also ensuring that the
language doesn't create unnecessary trade disagreements in a
time of economic crisis," Gibbs
said.
Scott Paul, executive director of AAM, said in a prepared
statement that the resulting language
was "a major victory for American manufacturers and workers."
He said: "Buy America is good
news for laid-off workers in construction and manufacturing,
and good news for the global
economy by helping to spur U.S. growth."
That's not how it was received overseas, however. Robert
Zoellick, president of the World Bank,
told The New York Times that it was crucial to avoid the
protectionist policies of the 1930s. "The
Buy American provision is very dangerous," he said. At the
Group of Seven meeting of world
financial leaders in Rome last week, U.S. Treasury Secretary
Timothy Geithner was pressed to
assure other countries that the Obama Administration would
remain committed to free trade.
http://www.businessweek.com/bwdaily/dnflash/content/feb2009/
db20090216_071307.htm
http://investing.businessweek.com/research/stocks/snapshot/sna
pshot.asp?symbol=GE
http://investing.businessweek.com/research/stocks/snapshot/sna
pshot.asp?symbol=CAT
http://www.businessweek.com/bwdaily/dnflash/content/jan2009/
db20090116_038195.htm
http://www.businessweek.com/bwdaily/dnflash/content/jan2009/
db20090116_038195.htm
http://www.businessweek.com/bwdaily/dnflash/content/jan2009/
db20090116_038195.htm
http://www.nytimes.com/2009/02/15/business/worldbusiness/15
g7.html
Tightening the H-1B Visa Program
Indeed, editorials from Europe to Asia blasted the symbolism of
the Buy American provision.
The Times of London called it "ugly," while China's Xinhua
news agency described it as "a
poison."
Debates around the stimulus bill also focused on proposals
relating to foreign workers. With U.S.
unemployment rising sharply, to 7.6% in January, some groups
and lawmakers were concerned
that jobs created by the bill might be outsourced or that they
wouldn't be filled with U.S.
workers. That sentiment led senators Charles Grassley (R-Iowa)
and Bernard Sanders (I-Vt.) to
propose an amendment that would restrict firms receiving TARP
money in their use of the
controversial H-1B visa program.
The final version of the bill included a measure that makes
these companies jump through extra
hoops in order to employ H-1B visa workers, but doesn't ban
them from doing so. Critics of the
H-1B program hailed the inclusion of the amendment as a
victory. "The demand to reform
corporate recruiting policies that ignore highly skilled local
talent now moves center stage," says
Donna Conroy, director of Brightfuturejobs.com, a lobbying
group for visa reform.
E-Verify Remains Voluntary
However, another measure aimed at preventing undocumented
workers from being employed in
stimulus-related work didn't make the final bill. That provision
would have required employers
receiving stimulus money to use the federal government's E-
Verify program—which is currently
voluntary—to ensure that job applicants are legally authorized
to work in the U.S.
The U.S. Chamber of Commerce and immigrant advocacy
groups lobbied against that rule,
arguing that the E-Verify program incorrectly identifies some
documented workers as
undocumented, and that it would cost too much to enforce.
"Expanding E-Verify before
improving it would have been a costly and chaotic mistake,"
says Michele Waslin, senior policy
analyst at the Immigration Policy Center.
Groups in favor of the provision expressed frustration that it
wasn't included. "It is almost absurd
to think that Congress is spending $800 billion to create 3 to 4
million jobs while not taking any
precautions to make sure they are filled by U.S. workers," says
Ira Mehlman, a spokesman for
the Federation for American Immigration Reform. "It's a clear
capitulation to pressure from the
Chamber of Commerce and its constituents who want to hire
labor as cheap as possible."
Herbst is a reporter for BusinessWeek in New York.
http://www.businessweek.com/bwdaily/dnflash/content/feb2009/
%20http:/www.timesonline.co.uk/tol/comment/leading_article/a
rticle5741121.ece
http://www.businessweek.com/bwdaily/dnflash/content/feb2009/
%20http:/www.businessweek.com/bwdaily/dnflash/content/feb2
009/db20090212_920784.htm
http://www.businessweek.com/blogs/money_politics/archives/20
09/02/stimulus_tighte.html
mailto:[email protected]
Protectionism
The battle of Smoot-Hawley
Dec 18th 2008
From The Economist print edition
A cautionary tale about how a protectionist
measure opposed by all right-thinking people
was passed
Library of Congress
Hawley and Smoot, the bogeymen of trade
EVEN when desperate, Wall Street bankers are not given to
grovelling. But in June
1930 Thomas Lamont, a partner at J.P. Morgan, came close. “I
almost went down
on my knees to beg Herbert Hoover to veto the asinine Hawley-
Smoot Tariff,” he
recalled. “That Act intensified nationalism all over the world.”
According to David Kennedy, an historian, Lamont was “usually
an influential
economic adviser” to the American president. Not this time.
Hoover signed the bill
on June 17th: “the tragic-comic finale”, said that week’s
Economist, “to one of the
most amazing chapters in world tariff history…one that
Protectionist enthusiasts the
world over would do well to study.”
The Tariff Act of 1930, which increased nearly 900 American
import duties, was
debated, passed and signed as the world was tumbling into the
Depression. Its
sponsors—Willis Hawley, a congressman from Oregon, and
Reed Smoot, a senator
from Utah—have come to personify the economic isolationism
of the era. Sixty-
three years later, in a television debate on the North American
Free-Trade
Agreement, Al Gore, then vice-president, even presented his
unamused anti-NAFTA
opponent, Ross Perot, with a framed photograph of the pair.
Now, with the world
economy in perhaps its worst pickle since the Depression, the
names of Hawley and
Smoot are cropping up again.
In fact, few economists think the Smoot-Hawley tariff (as it is
most often known)
was one of the principal causes of the Depression. Worse
mistakes were made,
largely out of a misplaced faith in the gold standard and
balanced budgets.
America’s tariffs were already high, and some other countries
were already
increasing their own.
Nevertheless, the act added poison to the emptying well of
global trade (see chart).
The worldwide protection of the 1930s took decades to
dismantle. And bad
monetary and fiscal policies were at least based on the
economic orthodoxy of the
day: economists would tear each other apart over the heresies of
John Maynard
Keynes. On protection, there was no such division. More than a
thousand
economists petitioned Hoover not to sign the Smoot-Hawley
bill. Bankers like
Lamont sided with them; so did editorialists by the score.
The “asinine” bill began as a much smaller beast: the plan was
to help American
agriculture, which had slumped in the early 1920s. Congress
passed several bills to
support prices and subsidise exports, but all were vetoed by
Calvin Coolidge,
Hoover’s predecessor. With no obvious logic—most American
farmers faced little
competition from imports—attention shifted to securing for
agriculture the same
sort of protection as for manufacturing, where tariffs were on
average twice as
high. To many of its supporters, “tariff equality” meant
reducing industrial duties as
well as raising those on farm goods. “But so soon as ever the
tariff schedules were
cast into the melting-pot of revision,” this newspaper wrote,
“logrollers and
politicians set to work stirring with all their might.”
Start rolling
In the 1928 election campaign Hoover and his fellow
Republicans promised to
revise the tariff. The Democrats, then the freer-trading party,
were unusually
acquiescent. After comfortable Republican wins in November,
Hawley, the chairman
of the House Ways and Means Committee, set to work. By the
time Hoover was
inaugurated in March 1929 and called a special session of
Congress to tackle the
tariff, his committee had gathered 43 days’, five nights’ and
11,000 pages’ worth of
testimony. The door was open to more than just farmers;
Hawley’s committee
heard mainly from small and medium-sized industrial
businesses.
The House bill, passed in May, raised 845 tariff rates and cut
82. Douglas Irwin, an
economist at Dartmouth and author of a forthcoming book (“The
Battle over
Protection: A History of US Trade Policy”) on which this article
draws heavily, says
it “tilted the tariff nearly as much toward higher duties on
manufactured goods as it
increased duties on agricultural imports.”
The bill then went to the Senate, where Smoot chaired the
Finance Committee.
Senators who thought their constituents had lost out in the
House—from farming
and mining states—were spoiling for a fight. Smoot’s
committee increased 177
rates from the House version and cut 254. In the next committee
stage—which
lasted from the autumn of 1929 until March 1930—the whole
Senate could take
part. Farming- and mining-state senators pruned Hawley’s
increases in industrial
tariffs.
In the last Senate stage, senators from industrial states
regrouped, fortified by the
gathering economic gloom. “A different voting coalition
emerged,” says Mr Irwin,
“not one based on agricultural versus industrial interests but on
classic vote-trading
among unrelated goods.” Some senators disapproved: Robert
LaFollette, a
Republican from Wisconsin, called the bill “the product of a
series of deals,
conceived in secret, but executed in public with a brazen
effrontery that is without
parallel in the annals of the Senate.”
Others saw nothing wrong. Charles Waterman, a Republican
from Colorado,
declared: “I have stated…that, by the eternal, I will not vote for
a tariff upon the
products of another state if the senators from that state vote
against protecting the
industries of my state.” The tariff’s critics—including Franklin
Roosevelt, in his
presidential campaign in 1932—dubbed the bill the “Grundy
tariff”, after Joseph
Grundy, a Republican senator from Pennsylvania and president
of the Pennsylvania
Manufacturers’ Association. Grundy had said that anyone who
made campaign
contributions was entitled to higher tariffs in return.
The Senate’s final bill contained no fewer than 1,253 changes
from the House’s
version. The two houses compromised, broadly by moving the
Senate’s rates up
rather than the House’s down. In all, 890 tariffs were increased,
compared with the
previous Tariff Act, of 1922, which had itself raised duties
dramatically (for
examples, see table); 235 were cut. The bill squeezed through
the Senate, by 44
votes to 42, and breezed through the House.
Of all the calls on Hoover not to sign the bill, perhaps the
weightiest was a petition
signed by 1,028 American economists. A dozen years later
Frank Fetter, one of the
organisers, recalled their unanimity. “Economic faculties that
within a few years
were to be split wide open on monetary policy, deficit finance,
and the problem of
big business, were practically at one in their belief that the
Hawley-Smoot bill was
an iniquitous piece of legislation.”
Some of the names are familiar even now. One was Frank
Taussig, a former head
of the Tariff Commission (which advised on whether duties
should be raised or
lowered). Another was Paul Douglas, later a senator
(undergraduates are still
introduced to the Cobb-Douglas production function). And a
third was Irving Fisher.
Fisher is still a giant of economics, best known for his work on
monetary theory and
index numbers. (He was fallible, though. Shortly before the
1929 stockmarket
crash, he declared, “Stock prices have reached what looks like a
permanently high
plateau.”) According to Fetter, Fisher suggested that the
petition refer explicitly to
the importance of trade to America as a huge creditor nation: if
other countries
could not sell to the United States, how could they repay their
debts? It was also
thanks to Fisher that so many economists signed it. He proposed
that it be sent to
the entire membership of the American Economic Association,
rather than to one
member of each university’s faculty, and offered to meet the
extra expense. The
total cost was $137, of which Fisher paid $105.
Expensive ink
Hoover’s signature cost rather more—even though the direct
effect on American
trade was limited. The average rate on dutiable goods rose from
40% to 48%,
implying a price increase of only 6%. And most trade, Mr Irwin
points out, was free
of duty (partly because high tariffs discouraged imports). He
estimates that the
new tariff reduced dutiable imports by 17-20% and the total by
4-6%. Yet the
volume of American imports had already dropped by 15% in the
year before the act
was passed. It would fall by a further 40% in a little more than
two years.
Other, bigger forces were at work. Chief among these was the
fall in American GDP,
the causes of which went far beyond protection. The other was
deflation, which
amplified the effects of the existing tariff and the Smoot-
Hawley increases. In those
days most tariffs were levied on the volume of imports (so many
cents per pound,
say) rather than value. So as deflation took hold after 1929,
effective tariff rates
climbed, discouraging imports. By 1932, the average American
tariff on dutiable
imports was 59.1%; only once before, in 1830, had it been
higher. Mr Irwin
reckons that the Tariff Act raised duties by 20%; deflation
accounted for half as
much again.
Smoot-Hawley did most harm by souring trade relations with
other countries. The
League of Nations, of which America was not a member, had
talked of a “tariff
truce”; the Tariff Act helped to undermine that idea. By
September 1929 the
Hoover administration had already noted protests from 23
trading partners at the
prospect of higher tariffs. But the threat of retaliation was
ignored: America’s tariffs
were America’s business. The Congressional Record, notes Mr
Irwin, contains 20
pages of debate on the duty on tomatoes but very little on the
reaction from
abroad.
A study by Judith McDonald, Anthony Patrick O’Brien and
Colleen Callahan*
examines the response of Canada, America’s biggest trading
partner. When Hoover
was elected president, the Canadian prime minister, Mackenzie
King, wrote in his
diary that his victory would lead to “border warfare”. King, who
had cut tariffs in
the early 1920s, warned the Americans that retaliation might
follow. In May 1930,
with higher American tariffs all but certain, he imposed extra
duties on some
American goods—and cut tariffs on imports from the rest of the
British empire.
He promptly called a general election, believing he had done
enough to satisfy
Canadians’ resentment. America, wrote the New York Times,
was “consciously
giving Canada inducements to turn to England for the goods
which she has been
buying from the United States.” Canadians agreed. King’s
Liberals were crushed by
the Conservatives, who favoured and enacted even higher
tariffs.
All this, of course, is history. There are plenty of reasons to
think that the terrible
lesson of the 1930s will not have to be learnt again.
Governments have reaffirmed
their commitment to open trade and the World Trade
Organisation (WTO). The
http://www.economist.com/finance/displaystory.cfm?story_id=1
2798595#footnote1
complex patterns of cross-border commerce, with myriad stages
of production
spread over so many countries, would be enormously costly to
pull apart.
And yet. Tariffs can be increased, even under the WTO. The use
of anti-dumping is
on the rise. Favours offered to one industry (farming then; cars
now?) can be hard
to refuse to others. And the fact that politicians know something
to be madness
does not stop them doing it. They were told in 1930: 1,028
times over.
The world economy
The return of economic nationalism
Feb 5th 2009
From The Economist print edition
A spectre is rising. To bury it again, Barack Obama needs
to take the lead
Illustration by Jon Berkeley
MANAGING a crisis as complex as this one has so far called
for nuance and pragmatism
rather than stridency and principle. Should governments prop up
credit markets by offering
guarantees or creating bad banks? Probably both. What package
of fiscal stimulus would be
most effective? It varies from one country to the next. Should
banks be nationalised? Yes,
in some circumstances. Only the foolish and the partisan have
rejected (or embraced) any
solutions categorically.
But the re-emergence of a spectre from the darkest period of
modern history argues for a
different, indeed strident, response. Economic nationalism—the
urge to keep jobs and
capital at home—is both turning the economic crisis into a
political one and threatening the
world with depression. If it is not buried again forthwith, the
consequences will be dire.
Devil take the hindmost
Trade encourages specialisation, which brings prosperity; global
capital markets, for all their
problems, allocate money more efficiently than local ones;
economic co-operation
encourages confidence and enhances security. Yet despite its
obvious benefits, the
globalised economy is under threat.
Congress is arguing about a clause in the $800 billion-plus
stimulus package that in its most
extreme form would press for the use of American materials in
public works. Earlier, Tim
Geithner, the new treasury secretary, accused China of
“manipulating” its currency,
prompting snarls from Beijing. Around the world, carmakers
have lobbied for support (see
article), and some have got it. A host of industries, in countries
from India to Ecuador, want
help from their governments.
The grip of nationalism is tightest in banking (see article). In
France and Britain, politicians
pouring taxpayers’ money into ailing banks are demanding that
the cash be lent at home.
Since banks are reducing overall lending, that means
repatriating cash. Regulators are
thinking nationally too. Switzerland now favours domestic loans
by ignoring them in one
measure of the capital its banks need to hold; foreign loans
count in full.
Governments protect goods and capital largely in order to
protect jobs. Around the world,
workers are demanding help from the state with increasing
panic. British strikers, quoting
Gordon Brown’s ill-chosen words back at him, are demanding
that he provide “British jobs
for British workers” (see article). In France more than 1m
people stayed away from work on
January 29th, marching for jobs and wages. In Greece police
used tear gas to control
farmers calling for even more subsidies.
Three arguments are raised in defence of economic nationalism:
that it is justified
commercially; that it is justified politically; and that it won’t
get very far. On the first point,
some damaged banks may feel safer retreating to their home
markets, where they
understand the risks and benefit from scale; but that is a trend
which governments should
seek to counteract, not to encourage. On the second point, it is
reasonable for politicians to
want to spend taxpayers’ money at home—so long as the costs
of doing so are not
unacceptably high.
In this case, however, the costs could be enormous. For the
third argument—that
protectionism will not get very far—is dangerously complacent.
True, everybody sensible
scoffs at Reed Smoot and Willis Hawley, the lawmakers who in
1930 exacerbated the
Depression by raising American tariffs. But reasonable people
opposed them at the time,
and failed to stop them: 1,028 economists petitioned against
their bill. Certainly, global
supply-chains are more complex and harder to pick apart than in
those days. But when
nationalism is on the march, even commercial logic gets
trampled underfoot.
The links that bind countries’ economies together are under
strain. World trade may well
shrink this year for the first time since 1982. Net private-sector
capital flows to the
emerging markets are likely to fall to $165 billion, from a peak
of $929 billion in 2007. Even
if there were no policies to undermine it, globalisation is
suffering its biggest reversal in the
modern era.
Politicians know that, with support for open markets low and
falling, they must be seen to
do something; and policies designed to put something right at
home can inadvertently eat
away at the global system. An attempt to prop up Ireland’s
banks last year sucked deposits
out of Britain’s. American plans to monitor domestic bank
lending month by month will
encourage lending at home rather than abroad. As countries try
to save themselves they
endanger each other.
The big question is what America will do. At some moments in
this crisis it has shown the
way—by agreeing to supply dollars to countries that needed
them, and by guaranteeing the
contracts of European banks when it rescued a big insurer. But
the “Buy American”
provisions in the stimulus bill are alarmingly nationalistic. They
would not even boost
American employment in the short run, because—just as with
Smoot-Hawley—the inevitable
retaliation would destroy more jobs at exporting firms. And the
political consequences would
http://www.economist.com/opinion/displaystory.cfm?story_id=1
3057275
http://www.economist.com/opinion/displaystory.cfm?story_id=1
3057265
http://www.economist.com/opinion/displaystory.cfm?story_id=1
3061705
be far worse than the economic ones. They would send a
disastrous signal to the rest of the
world: the champion of open markets is going it alone.
A time to act
Barack Obama says that he doesn’t like “Buy American” (and
the provisions have been
softened in the Senate’s version of the stimulus plan). That’s
good—but not enough. Mr
Obama should veto the entire package unless they are removed.
And he must go further, by
championing three principles.
The first principle is co-ordination—especially in rescue
packages, like the one that helped
the rich world’s banks last year. Countries’ stimulus plans
should be built around common
principles, even if they differ in the details. Co-ordination is
good economics, as well as
good politics: combined plans are also more economically
potent than national ones.
The second principle is forbearance. Each nation’s stimulus
plan should embrace open
markets, even if some foreigners will benefit. Similarly,
financial regulators should leave the
re-regulation of cross-border banking until later, at an
international level, rather than
beggaring their neighbours by grabbing scarce capital, setting
targets for domestic lending
and drawing up rules with long-term consequences now.
The third principle is multilateralism. The IMF and the
development banks should help to
meet emerging markets’ shortfall in capital. They need the
structure and the resources to
do so. The World Trade Organisation can help to shore up the
trading system if its members
pledge to complete the Doha round of trade talks and make good
on their promise at last
year’s G20 meeting to put aside the arsenal of trade sanctions.
When economic conflict seems more likely than ever, what can
persuade countries to give
up their trade weapons? American leadership is the only chance.
The international economic
system depends upon a guarantor, prepared to back it during
crises. In the 19th century
Britain played that part. Nobody did between the wars, and the
consequences were
disastrous. Partly because of that mistake, America bravely
sponsored a new economic
order after the second world war.
Once again, the task of saving the world economy falls to
America. Mr Obama must show
that he is ready for it. If he is, he should kill any “Buy
American” provisions. If he isn’t,
America and the rest of the world are in deep trouble.
Jobs and Protectionism in the Stimulus Package Preside.docx

More Related Content

Similar to Jobs and Protectionism in the Stimulus Package Preside.docx

Chapter11Economic Instruments271Dateline New NAFTAD
Chapter11Economic Instruments271Dateline New NAFTADChapter11Economic Instruments271Dateline New NAFTAD
Chapter11Economic Instruments271Dateline New NAFTADJinElias52
 
SteelCompanies-Aug -5
SteelCompanies-Aug -5SteelCompanies-Aug -5
SteelCompanies-Aug -5Dave Boe
 
Trade War - An Overview
Trade War - An OverviewTrade War - An Overview
Trade War - An Overviewijtsrd
 
Trade between the U.S. and China
Trade between the U.S. and ChinaTrade between the U.S. and China
Trade between the U.S. and ChinaMatt Laidlaw
 
TRADE TRIALS AND TRIUMPHSMale SpeakerInternational tr.docx
TRADE TRIALS AND TRIUMPHSMale SpeakerInternational tr.docxTRADE TRIALS AND TRIUMPHSMale SpeakerInternational tr.docx
TRADE TRIALS AND TRIUMPHSMale SpeakerInternational tr.docxturveycharlyn
 
1. How do domestic considerations make foreign and security polici.docx
1. How do domestic considerations make foreign and security polici.docx1. How do domestic considerations make foreign and security polici.docx
1. How do domestic considerations make foreign and security polici.docxSONU61709
 

Similar to Jobs and Protectionism in the Stimulus Package Preside.docx (10)

Essays On Teacher.pdf
Essays On Teacher.pdfEssays On Teacher.pdf
Essays On Teacher.pdf
 
Chapter11Economic Instruments271Dateline New NAFTAD
Chapter11Economic Instruments271Dateline New NAFTADChapter11Economic Instruments271Dateline New NAFTAD
Chapter11Economic Instruments271Dateline New NAFTAD
 
Tariffed !
Tariffed !Tariffed !
Tariffed !
 
SteelCompanies-Aug -5
SteelCompanies-Aug -5SteelCompanies-Aug -5
SteelCompanies-Aug -5
 
Trade War - An Overview
Trade War - An OverviewTrade War - An Overview
Trade War - An Overview
 
Trade between the U.S. and China
Trade between the U.S. and ChinaTrade between the U.S. and China
Trade between the U.S. and China
 
Scenari - Umberto Bertelé
Scenari - Umberto BerteléScenari - Umberto Bertelé
Scenari - Umberto Bertelé
 
TRADE TRIALS AND TRIUMPHSMale SpeakerInternational tr.docx
TRADE TRIALS AND TRIUMPHSMale SpeakerInternational tr.docxTRADE TRIALS AND TRIUMPHSMale SpeakerInternational tr.docx
TRADE TRIALS AND TRIUMPHSMale SpeakerInternational tr.docx
 
1. How do domestic considerations make foreign and security polici.docx
1. How do domestic considerations make foreign and security polici.docx1. How do domestic considerations make foreign and security polici.docx
1. How do domestic considerations make foreign and security polici.docx
 
Press Review Us Economic Crisis July 3rd 2008
Press Review Us Economic Crisis July 3rd 2008Press Review Us Economic Crisis July 3rd 2008
Press Review Us Economic Crisis July 3rd 2008
 

More from christiandean12115

100 Original WorkZero PlagiarismGraduate Level Writing Required.docx
100 Original WorkZero PlagiarismGraduate Level Writing Required.docx100 Original WorkZero PlagiarismGraduate Level Writing Required.docx
100 Original WorkZero PlagiarismGraduate Level Writing Required.docxchristiandean12115
 
10.11771066480704270150THE FAMILY JOURNAL COUNSELING AND THE.docx
10.11771066480704270150THE FAMILY JOURNAL COUNSELING AND THE.docx10.11771066480704270150THE FAMILY JOURNAL COUNSELING AND THE.docx
10.11771066480704270150THE FAMILY JOURNAL COUNSELING AND THE.docxchristiandean12115
 
10.11771066480703252339 ARTICLETHE FAMILY JOURNAL COUNSELING.docx
10.11771066480703252339 ARTICLETHE FAMILY JOURNAL COUNSELING.docx10.11771066480703252339 ARTICLETHE FAMILY JOURNAL COUNSELING.docx
10.11771066480703252339 ARTICLETHE FAMILY JOURNAL COUNSELING.docxchristiandean12115
 
10.11770022427803260263ARTICLEJOURNAL OF RESEARCH IN CRIME AN.docx
10.11770022427803260263ARTICLEJOURNAL OF RESEARCH IN CRIME AN.docx10.11770022427803260263ARTICLEJOURNAL OF RESEARCH IN CRIME AN.docx
10.11770022427803260263ARTICLEJOURNAL OF RESEARCH IN CRIME AN.docxchristiandean12115
 
10.11770022487105285962Journal of Teacher Education, Vol. 57,.docx
10.11770022487105285962Journal of Teacher Education, Vol. 57,.docx10.11770022487105285962Journal of Teacher Education, Vol. 57,.docx
10.11770022487105285962Journal of Teacher Education, Vol. 57,.docxchristiandean12115
 
10.11770011000002250638ARTICLETHE COUNSELING PSYCHOLOGIST M.docx
10.11770011000002250638ARTICLETHE COUNSELING PSYCHOLOGIST  M.docx10.11770011000002250638ARTICLETHE COUNSELING PSYCHOLOGIST  M.docx
10.11770011000002250638ARTICLETHE COUNSELING PSYCHOLOGIST M.docxchristiandean12115
 
10.1 What are three broad mechanisms that malware can use to propa.docx
10.1 What are three broad mechanisms that malware can use to propa.docx10.1 What are three broad mechanisms that malware can use to propa.docx
10.1 What are three broad mechanisms that malware can use to propa.docxchristiandean12115
 
10.0 ptsPresentation of information was exceptional and included.docx
10.0 ptsPresentation of information was exceptional and included.docx10.0 ptsPresentation of information was exceptional and included.docx
10.0 ptsPresentation of information was exceptional and included.docxchristiandean12115
 
10-K1f12312012-10k.htm10-KUNITED STATESSECURIT.docx
10-K1f12312012-10k.htm10-KUNITED STATESSECURIT.docx10-K1f12312012-10k.htm10-KUNITED STATESSECURIT.docx
10-K1f12312012-10k.htm10-KUNITED STATESSECURIT.docxchristiandean12115
 
10-K 1 f12312012-10k.htm 10-K UNITED STATESSECURITIES AN.docx
10-K 1 f12312012-10k.htm 10-K UNITED STATESSECURITIES AN.docx10-K 1 f12312012-10k.htm 10-K UNITED STATESSECURITIES AN.docx
10-K 1 f12312012-10k.htm 10-K UNITED STATESSECURITIES AN.docxchristiandean12115
 
10 What does a golfer, tennis player or cricketer (or any othe.docx
10 What does a golfer, tennis player or cricketer (or any othe.docx10 What does a golfer, tennis player or cricketer (or any othe.docx
10 What does a golfer, tennis player or cricketer (or any othe.docxchristiandean12115
 
10 September 2018· Watch video· Take notes withfor students.docx
10 September 2018· Watch video· Take notes withfor students.docx10 September 2018· Watch video· Take notes withfor students.docx
10 September 2018· Watch video· Take notes withfor students.docxchristiandean12115
 
10 Research-Based Tips for Enhancing Literacy Instruct.docx
10 Research-Based Tips for Enhancing Literacy Instruct.docx10 Research-Based Tips for Enhancing Literacy Instruct.docx
10 Research-Based Tips for Enhancing Literacy Instruct.docxchristiandean12115
 
10 Strategic Points for the Prospectus, Proposal, and Direct Pract.docx
10 Strategic Points for the Prospectus, Proposal, and Direct Pract.docx10 Strategic Points for the Prospectus, Proposal, and Direct Pract.docx
10 Strategic Points for the Prospectus, Proposal, and Direct Pract.docxchristiandean12115
 
10 Introduction Ask any IT manager about the chall.docx
10 Introduction Ask any IT manager about the chall.docx10 Introduction Ask any IT manager about the chall.docx
10 Introduction Ask any IT manager about the chall.docxchristiandean12115
 
10 Customer Acquisition and Relationship ManagementDmitry .docx
10 Customer Acquisition and Relationship ManagementDmitry .docx10 Customer Acquisition and Relationship ManagementDmitry .docx
10 Customer Acquisition and Relationship ManagementDmitry .docxchristiandean12115
 
10 ELEMENTS OF LITERATURE (FROM A TO Z)   1  ​PLOT​ (seri.docx
10 ELEMENTS OF LITERATURE (FROM A TO Z)   1  ​PLOT​  (seri.docx10 ELEMENTS OF LITERATURE (FROM A TO Z)   1  ​PLOT​  (seri.docx
10 ELEMENTS OF LITERATURE (FROM A TO Z)   1  ​PLOT​ (seri.docxchristiandean12115
 
10 ers. Although one can learn definitions favor- able to .docx
10 ers. Although one can learn definitions favor- able to .docx10 ers. Although one can learn definitions favor- able to .docx
10 ers. Although one can learn definitions favor- able to .docxchristiandean12115
 
10 academic sources about the topic (Why is America so violent).docx
10 academic sources about the topic (Why is America so violent).docx10 academic sources about the topic (Why is America so violent).docx
10 academic sources about the topic (Why is America so violent).docxchristiandean12115
 

More from christiandean12115 (20)

100 Original WorkZero PlagiarismGraduate Level Writing Required.docx
100 Original WorkZero PlagiarismGraduate Level Writing Required.docx100 Original WorkZero PlagiarismGraduate Level Writing Required.docx
100 Original WorkZero PlagiarismGraduate Level Writing Required.docx
 
10.11771066480704270150THE FAMILY JOURNAL COUNSELING AND THE.docx
10.11771066480704270150THE FAMILY JOURNAL COUNSELING AND THE.docx10.11771066480704270150THE FAMILY JOURNAL COUNSELING AND THE.docx
10.11771066480704270150THE FAMILY JOURNAL COUNSELING AND THE.docx
 
10.11771066480703252339 ARTICLETHE FAMILY JOURNAL COUNSELING.docx
10.11771066480703252339 ARTICLETHE FAMILY JOURNAL COUNSELING.docx10.11771066480703252339 ARTICLETHE FAMILY JOURNAL COUNSELING.docx
10.11771066480703252339 ARTICLETHE FAMILY JOURNAL COUNSELING.docx
 
10.11770022427803260263ARTICLEJOURNAL OF RESEARCH IN CRIME AN.docx
10.11770022427803260263ARTICLEJOURNAL OF RESEARCH IN CRIME AN.docx10.11770022427803260263ARTICLEJOURNAL OF RESEARCH IN CRIME AN.docx
10.11770022427803260263ARTICLEJOURNAL OF RESEARCH IN CRIME AN.docx
 
10.11770022487105285962Journal of Teacher Education, Vol. 57,.docx
10.11770022487105285962Journal of Teacher Education, Vol. 57,.docx10.11770022487105285962Journal of Teacher Education, Vol. 57,.docx
10.11770022487105285962Journal of Teacher Education, Vol. 57,.docx
 
10.11770011000002250638ARTICLETHE COUNSELING PSYCHOLOGIST M.docx
10.11770011000002250638ARTICLETHE COUNSELING PSYCHOLOGIST  M.docx10.11770011000002250638ARTICLETHE COUNSELING PSYCHOLOGIST  M.docx
10.11770011000002250638ARTICLETHE COUNSELING PSYCHOLOGIST M.docx
 
10.1 What are three broad mechanisms that malware can use to propa.docx
10.1 What are three broad mechanisms that malware can use to propa.docx10.1 What are three broad mechanisms that malware can use to propa.docx
10.1 What are three broad mechanisms that malware can use to propa.docx
 
10.0 ptsPresentation of information was exceptional and included.docx
10.0 ptsPresentation of information was exceptional and included.docx10.0 ptsPresentation of information was exceptional and included.docx
10.0 ptsPresentation of information was exceptional and included.docx
 
10-K1f12312012-10k.htm10-KUNITED STATESSECURIT.docx
10-K1f12312012-10k.htm10-KUNITED STATESSECURIT.docx10-K1f12312012-10k.htm10-KUNITED STATESSECURIT.docx
10-K1f12312012-10k.htm10-KUNITED STATESSECURIT.docx
 
10-K 1 f12312012-10k.htm 10-K UNITED STATESSECURITIES AN.docx
10-K 1 f12312012-10k.htm 10-K UNITED STATESSECURITIES AN.docx10-K 1 f12312012-10k.htm 10-K UNITED STATESSECURITIES AN.docx
10-K 1 f12312012-10k.htm 10-K UNITED STATESSECURITIES AN.docx
 
10 What does a golfer, tennis player or cricketer (or any othe.docx
10 What does a golfer, tennis player or cricketer (or any othe.docx10 What does a golfer, tennis player or cricketer (or any othe.docx
10 What does a golfer, tennis player or cricketer (or any othe.docx
 
10 September 2018· Watch video· Take notes withfor students.docx
10 September 2018· Watch video· Take notes withfor students.docx10 September 2018· Watch video· Take notes withfor students.docx
10 September 2018· Watch video· Take notes withfor students.docx
 
10 Research-Based Tips for Enhancing Literacy Instruct.docx
10 Research-Based Tips for Enhancing Literacy Instruct.docx10 Research-Based Tips for Enhancing Literacy Instruct.docx
10 Research-Based Tips for Enhancing Literacy Instruct.docx
 
10 Strategic Points for the Prospectus, Proposal, and Direct Pract.docx
10 Strategic Points for the Prospectus, Proposal, and Direct Pract.docx10 Strategic Points for the Prospectus, Proposal, and Direct Pract.docx
10 Strategic Points for the Prospectus, Proposal, and Direct Pract.docx
 
10 Most Common Err.docx
10 Most Common Err.docx10 Most Common Err.docx
10 Most Common Err.docx
 
10 Introduction Ask any IT manager about the chall.docx
10 Introduction Ask any IT manager about the chall.docx10 Introduction Ask any IT manager about the chall.docx
10 Introduction Ask any IT manager about the chall.docx
 
10 Customer Acquisition and Relationship ManagementDmitry .docx
10 Customer Acquisition and Relationship ManagementDmitry .docx10 Customer Acquisition and Relationship ManagementDmitry .docx
10 Customer Acquisition and Relationship ManagementDmitry .docx
 
10 ELEMENTS OF LITERATURE (FROM A TO Z)   1  ​PLOT​ (seri.docx
10 ELEMENTS OF LITERATURE (FROM A TO Z)   1  ​PLOT​  (seri.docx10 ELEMENTS OF LITERATURE (FROM A TO Z)   1  ​PLOT​  (seri.docx
10 ELEMENTS OF LITERATURE (FROM A TO Z)   1  ​PLOT​ (seri.docx
 
10 ers. Although one can learn definitions favor- able to .docx
10 ers. Although one can learn definitions favor- able to .docx10 ers. Although one can learn definitions favor- able to .docx
10 ers. Although one can learn definitions favor- able to .docx
 
10 academic sources about the topic (Why is America so violent).docx
10 academic sources about the topic (Why is America so violent).docx10 academic sources about the topic (Why is America so violent).docx
10 academic sources about the topic (Why is America so violent).docx
 

Recently uploaded

Proudly South Africa powerpoint Thorisha.pptx
Proudly South Africa powerpoint Thorisha.pptxProudly South Africa powerpoint Thorisha.pptx
Proudly South Africa powerpoint Thorisha.pptxthorishapillay1
 
Crayon Activity Handout For the Crayon A
Crayon Activity Handout For the Crayon ACrayon Activity Handout For the Crayon A
Crayon Activity Handout For the Crayon AUnboundStockton
 
Science 7 - LAND and SEA BREEZE and its Characteristics
Science 7 - LAND and SEA BREEZE and its CharacteristicsScience 7 - LAND and SEA BREEZE and its Characteristics
Science 7 - LAND and SEA BREEZE and its CharacteristicsKarinaGenton
 
Painted Grey Ware.pptx, PGW Culture of India
Painted Grey Ware.pptx, PGW Culture of IndiaPainted Grey Ware.pptx, PGW Culture of India
Painted Grey Ware.pptx, PGW Culture of IndiaVirag Sontakke
 
Hybridoma Technology ( Production , Purification , and Application )
Hybridoma Technology  ( Production , Purification , and Application  ) Hybridoma Technology  ( Production , Purification , and Application  )
Hybridoma Technology ( Production , Purification , and Application ) Sakshi Ghasle
 
How to Make a Pirate ship Primary Education.pptx
How to Make a Pirate ship Primary Education.pptxHow to Make a Pirate ship Primary Education.pptx
How to Make a Pirate ship Primary Education.pptxmanuelaromero2013
 
History Class XII Ch. 3 Kinship, Caste and Class (1).pptx
History Class XII Ch. 3 Kinship, Caste and Class (1).pptxHistory Class XII Ch. 3 Kinship, Caste and Class (1).pptx
History Class XII Ch. 3 Kinship, Caste and Class (1).pptxsocialsciencegdgrohi
 
Science lesson Moon for 4th quarter lesson
Science lesson Moon for 4th quarter lessonScience lesson Moon for 4th quarter lesson
Science lesson Moon for 4th quarter lessonJericReyAuditor
 
_Math 4-Q4 Week 5.pptx Steps in Collecting Data
_Math 4-Q4 Week 5.pptx Steps in Collecting Data_Math 4-Q4 Week 5.pptx Steps in Collecting Data
_Math 4-Q4 Week 5.pptx Steps in Collecting DataJhengPantaleon
 
How to Configure Email Server in Odoo 17
How to Configure Email Server in Odoo 17How to Configure Email Server in Odoo 17
How to Configure Email Server in Odoo 17Celine George
 
Mastering the Unannounced Regulatory Inspection
Mastering the Unannounced Regulatory InspectionMastering the Unannounced Regulatory Inspection
Mastering the Unannounced Regulatory InspectionSafetyChain Software
 
SOCIAL AND HISTORICAL CONTEXT - LFTVD.pptx
SOCIAL AND HISTORICAL CONTEXT - LFTVD.pptxSOCIAL AND HISTORICAL CONTEXT - LFTVD.pptx
SOCIAL AND HISTORICAL CONTEXT - LFTVD.pptxiammrhaywood
 
Sanyam Choudhary Chemistry practical.pdf
Sanyam Choudhary Chemistry practical.pdfSanyam Choudhary Chemistry practical.pdf
Sanyam Choudhary Chemistry practical.pdfsanyamsingh5019
 
18-04-UA_REPORT_MEDIALITERAСY_INDEX-DM_23-1-final-eng.pdf
18-04-UA_REPORT_MEDIALITERAСY_INDEX-DM_23-1-final-eng.pdf18-04-UA_REPORT_MEDIALITERAСY_INDEX-DM_23-1-final-eng.pdf
18-04-UA_REPORT_MEDIALITERAСY_INDEX-DM_23-1-final-eng.pdfssuser54595a
 
Solving Puzzles Benefits Everyone (English).pptx
Solving Puzzles Benefits Everyone (English).pptxSolving Puzzles Benefits Everyone (English).pptx
Solving Puzzles Benefits Everyone (English).pptxOH TEIK BIN
 
Introduction to AI in Higher Education_draft.pptx
Introduction to AI in Higher Education_draft.pptxIntroduction to AI in Higher Education_draft.pptx
Introduction to AI in Higher Education_draft.pptxpboyjonauth
 
Introduction to ArtificiaI Intelligence in Higher Education
Introduction to ArtificiaI Intelligence in Higher EducationIntroduction to ArtificiaI Intelligence in Higher Education
Introduction to ArtificiaI Intelligence in Higher Educationpboyjonauth
 
Presiding Officer Training module 2024 lok sabha elections
Presiding Officer Training module 2024 lok sabha electionsPresiding Officer Training module 2024 lok sabha elections
Presiding Officer Training module 2024 lok sabha electionsanshu789521
 
Incoming and Outgoing Shipments in 1 STEP Using Odoo 17
Incoming and Outgoing Shipments in 1 STEP Using Odoo 17Incoming and Outgoing Shipments in 1 STEP Using Odoo 17
Incoming and Outgoing Shipments in 1 STEP Using Odoo 17Celine George
 

Recently uploaded (20)

Proudly South Africa powerpoint Thorisha.pptx
Proudly South Africa powerpoint Thorisha.pptxProudly South Africa powerpoint Thorisha.pptx
Proudly South Africa powerpoint Thorisha.pptx
 
Crayon Activity Handout For the Crayon A
Crayon Activity Handout For the Crayon ACrayon Activity Handout For the Crayon A
Crayon Activity Handout For the Crayon A
 
Science 7 - LAND and SEA BREEZE and its Characteristics
Science 7 - LAND and SEA BREEZE and its CharacteristicsScience 7 - LAND and SEA BREEZE and its Characteristics
Science 7 - LAND and SEA BREEZE and its Characteristics
 
Painted Grey Ware.pptx, PGW Culture of India
Painted Grey Ware.pptx, PGW Culture of IndiaPainted Grey Ware.pptx, PGW Culture of India
Painted Grey Ware.pptx, PGW Culture of India
 
Hybridoma Technology ( Production , Purification , and Application )
Hybridoma Technology  ( Production , Purification , and Application  ) Hybridoma Technology  ( Production , Purification , and Application  )
Hybridoma Technology ( Production , Purification , and Application )
 
How to Make a Pirate ship Primary Education.pptx
How to Make a Pirate ship Primary Education.pptxHow to Make a Pirate ship Primary Education.pptx
How to Make a Pirate ship Primary Education.pptx
 
History Class XII Ch. 3 Kinship, Caste and Class (1).pptx
History Class XII Ch. 3 Kinship, Caste and Class (1).pptxHistory Class XII Ch. 3 Kinship, Caste and Class (1).pptx
History Class XII Ch. 3 Kinship, Caste and Class (1).pptx
 
Science lesson Moon for 4th quarter lesson
Science lesson Moon for 4th quarter lessonScience lesson Moon for 4th quarter lesson
Science lesson Moon for 4th quarter lesson
 
_Math 4-Q4 Week 5.pptx Steps in Collecting Data
_Math 4-Q4 Week 5.pptx Steps in Collecting Data_Math 4-Q4 Week 5.pptx Steps in Collecting Data
_Math 4-Q4 Week 5.pptx Steps in Collecting Data
 
How to Configure Email Server in Odoo 17
How to Configure Email Server in Odoo 17How to Configure Email Server in Odoo 17
How to Configure Email Server in Odoo 17
 
Mastering the Unannounced Regulatory Inspection
Mastering the Unannounced Regulatory InspectionMastering the Unannounced Regulatory Inspection
Mastering the Unannounced Regulatory Inspection
 
SOCIAL AND HISTORICAL CONTEXT - LFTVD.pptx
SOCIAL AND HISTORICAL CONTEXT - LFTVD.pptxSOCIAL AND HISTORICAL CONTEXT - LFTVD.pptx
SOCIAL AND HISTORICAL CONTEXT - LFTVD.pptx
 
Sanyam Choudhary Chemistry practical.pdf
Sanyam Choudhary Chemistry practical.pdfSanyam Choudhary Chemistry practical.pdf
Sanyam Choudhary Chemistry practical.pdf
 
18-04-UA_REPORT_MEDIALITERAСY_INDEX-DM_23-1-final-eng.pdf
18-04-UA_REPORT_MEDIALITERAСY_INDEX-DM_23-1-final-eng.pdf18-04-UA_REPORT_MEDIALITERAСY_INDEX-DM_23-1-final-eng.pdf
18-04-UA_REPORT_MEDIALITERAСY_INDEX-DM_23-1-final-eng.pdf
 
Model Call Girl in Bikash Puri Delhi reach out to us at 🔝9953056974🔝
Model Call Girl in Bikash Puri  Delhi reach out to us at 🔝9953056974🔝Model Call Girl in Bikash Puri  Delhi reach out to us at 🔝9953056974🔝
Model Call Girl in Bikash Puri Delhi reach out to us at 🔝9953056974🔝
 
Solving Puzzles Benefits Everyone (English).pptx
Solving Puzzles Benefits Everyone (English).pptxSolving Puzzles Benefits Everyone (English).pptx
Solving Puzzles Benefits Everyone (English).pptx
 
Introduction to AI in Higher Education_draft.pptx
Introduction to AI in Higher Education_draft.pptxIntroduction to AI in Higher Education_draft.pptx
Introduction to AI in Higher Education_draft.pptx
 
Introduction to ArtificiaI Intelligence in Higher Education
Introduction to ArtificiaI Intelligence in Higher EducationIntroduction to ArtificiaI Intelligence in Higher Education
Introduction to ArtificiaI Intelligence in Higher Education
 
Presiding Officer Training module 2024 lok sabha elections
Presiding Officer Training module 2024 lok sabha electionsPresiding Officer Training module 2024 lok sabha elections
Presiding Officer Training module 2024 lok sabha elections
 
Incoming and Outgoing Shipments in 1 STEP Using Odoo 17
Incoming and Outgoing Shipments in 1 STEP Using Odoo 17Incoming and Outgoing Shipments in 1 STEP Using Odoo 17
Incoming and Outgoing Shipments in 1 STEP Using Odoo 17
 

Jobs and Protectionism in the Stimulus Package Preside.docx

  • 1. Jobs and Protectionism in the Stimulus Package President Obama's spending bill promotes the use of American goods and labor. Despite foreign and domestic protests, the language is mainly rhetorical Members of the Senate and the House hash out differences between the two versions of the economic stimulus legislation at the U.S. Capitol on Feb. 11 Chip Somodevilla/Getty Images By Moira Herbst The $787 billion spending legislation being signed on Feb. 17 by President Barack Obama is designed to jolt some life into a moribund economy. Already, though, provisions to use the money to "buy American"—whether that means American iron, steel, or labor—is sparking a debate about whether such rules in a global economy amount to protectionism. Organized labor and small U.S. manufacturers won an
  • 2. amendment to the stimulus bill to ensure that more materials used on construction and infrastructure are made in the U.S. Critics of the H- 1B visa program won tougher rules governing when banks that are bailed out by the Troubled Assets Relief Program (TARP) can fill jobs with skilled immigrants. The final language drew criticism from abroad, where editorials and government officials warned it could run afoul of trade agreements. But both provisions are less stringent than earlier versions had been, and neither is likely to have a radical effect on how stimulus spending takes shape. http://www.businessweek.com/bios/Moira_Herbst.htm Opposition from Exporters The clearest attempt to wall off foreign companies from U.S. spending came in a "Buy American" provision. That rule requires that only U.S. iron, steel, and other manufactured goods be used for public buildings and public works funded under the bill. However, it comes with
  • 3. several key caveats. For one, the language states that the Buy American policy must not violate U.S. obligations under existing international trade agreements. Nor does the rule apply if American goods aren't available in sufficient quantities or if they'll increase the cost of the overall project by more than 25%. Federal highway, transit, and airport projects are already covered by similar Buy American requirements. The battle over the provision had been contentious. On Feb. 3, 100 business groups and companies—including the U.S. Chamber of Commerce, General Electric (GE), Caterpillar (CAT), and other major construction, defense, and high-tech companies—wrote a letter to Senate leaders warning that a far-reaching Buy American rule "will harm American workers and companies across the entire U.S. economy, undermine U.S. global engagement, and result in mirror-image trade restrictions abroad that would put at risk huge amounts of American exports." But advocates of the provision—including the Alliance for American Manufacturing, a partnership of manufacturing companies and the United
  • 4. Steelworkers union—said such rules are needed to stem the tide of layoffs in the U.S. construction and manufacturing sectors. Coalition Claims 'Major Victory' In negotiations, the Obama Administration sought to reconcile the opposing sides. White House spokesman Robert Gibbs told reporters on Feb. 12 that the final bill achieves this. "I think where we ended up with the Buy America provision is the right compromise that respects the Buy America laws that we've had on our books for many, many years while also ensuring that the language doesn't create unnecessary trade disagreements in a time of economic crisis," Gibbs said. Scott Paul, executive director of AAM, said in a prepared statement that the resulting language was "a major victory for American manufacturers and workers." He said: "Buy America is good news for laid-off workers in construction and manufacturing, and good news for the global economy by helping to spur U.S. growth." That's not how it was received overseas, however. Robert
  • 5. Zoellick, president of the World Bank, told The New York Times that it was crucial to avoid the protectionist policies of the 1930s. "The Buy American provision is very dangerous," he said. At the Group of Seven meeting of world financial leaders in Rome last week, U.S. Treasury Secretary Timothy Geithner was pressed to assure other countries that the Obama Administration would remain committed to free trade. http://www.businessweek.com/bwdaily/dnflash/content/feb2009/ db20090216_071307.htm http://investing.businessweek.com/research/stocks/snapshot/sna pshot.asp?symbol=GE http://investing.businessweek.com/research/stocks/snapshot/sna pshot.asp?symbol=CAT http://www.businessweek.com/bwdaily/dnflash/content/jan2009/ db20090116_038195.htm http://www.businessweek.com/bwdaily/dnflash/content/jan2009/ db20090116_038195.htm http://www.businessweek.com/bwdaily/dnflash/content/jan2009/ db20090116_038195.htm http://www.nytimes.com/2009/02/15/business/worldbusiness/15 g7.html Tightening the H-1B Visa Program Indeed, editorials from Europe to Asia blasted the symbolism of the Buy American provision.
  • 6. The Times of London called it "ugly," while China's Xinhua news agency described it as "a poison." Debates around the stimulus bill also focused on proposals relating to foreign workers. With U.S. unemployment rising sharply, to 7.6% in January, some groups and lawmakers were concerned that jobs created by the bill might be outsourced or that they wouldn't be filled with U.S. workers. That sentiment led senators Charles Grassley (R-Iowa) and Bernard Sanders (I-Vt.) to propose an amendment that would restrict firms receiving TARP money in their use of the controversial H-1B visa program. The final version of the bill included a measure that makes these companies jump through extra hoops in order to employ H-1B visa workers, but doesn't ban them from doing so. Critics of the H-1B program hailed the inclusion of the amendment as a victory. "The demand to reform corporate recruiting policies that ignore highly skilled local talent now moves center stage," says Donna Conroy, director of Brightfuturejobs.com, a lobbying group for visa reform.
  • 7. E-Verify Remains Voluntary However, another measure aimed at preventing undocumented workers from being employed in stimulus-related work didn't make the final bill. That provision would have required employers receiving stimulus money to use the federal government's E- Verify program—which is currently voluntary—to ensure that job applicants are legally authorized to work in the U.S. The U.S. Chamber of Commerce and immigrant advocacy groups lobbied against that rule, arguing that the E-Verify program incorrectly identifies some documented workers as undocumented, and that it would cost too much to enforce. "Expanding E-Verify before improving it would have been a costly and chaotic mistake," says Michele Waslin, senior policy analyst at the Immigration Policy Center. Groups in favor of the provision expressed frustration that it wasn't included. "It is almost absurd to think that Congress is spending $800 billion to create 3 to 4 million jobs while not taking any precautions to make sure they are filled by U.S. workers," says
  • 8. Ira Mehlman, a spokesman for the Federation for American Immigration Reform. "It's a clear capitulation to pressure from the Chamber of Commerce and its constituents who want to hire labor as cheap as possible." Herbst is a reporter for BusinessWeek in New York. http://www.businessweek.com/bwdaily/dnflash/content/feb2009/ %20http:/www.timesonline.co.uk/tol/comment/leading_article/a rticle5741121.ece http://www.businessweek.com/bwdaily/dnflash/content/feb2009/ %20http:/www.businessweek.com/bwdaily/dnflash/content/feb2 009/db20090212_920784.htm http://www.businessweek.com/blogs/money_politics/archives/20 09/02/stimulus_tighte.html mailto:[email protected] Protectionism The battle of Smoot-Hawley Dec 18th 2008 From The Economist print edition A cautionary tale about how a protectionist measure opposed by all right-thinking people was passed
  • 9. Library of Congress Hawley and Smoot, the bogeymen of trade EVEN when desperate, Wall Street bankers are not given to grovelling. But in June 1930 Thomas Lamont, a partner at J.P. Morgan, came close. “I almost went down on my knees to beg Herbert Hoover to veto the asinine Hawley- Smoot Tariff,” he recalled. “That Act intensified nationalism all over the world.” According to David Kennedy, an historian, Lamont was “usually an influential economic adviser” to the American president. Not this time. Hoover signed the bill on June 17th: “the tragic-comic finale”, said that week’s Economist, “to one of the most amazing chapters in world tariff history…one that Protectionist enthusiasts the world over would do well to study.” The Tariff Act of 1930, which increased nearly 900 American import duties, was debated, passed and signed as the world was tumbling into the Depression. Its sponsors—Willis Hawley, a congressman from Oregon, and Reed Smoot, a senator from Utah—have come to personify the economic isolationism of the era. Sixty- three years later, in a television debate on the North American Free-Trade
  • 10. Agreement, Al Gore, then vice-president, even presented his unamused anti-NAFTA opponent, Ross Perot, with a framed photograph of the pair. Now, with the world economy in perhaps its worst pickle since the Depression, the names of Hawley and Smoot are cropping up again. In fact, few economists think the Smoot-Hawley tariff (as it is most often known) was one of the principal causes of the Depression. Worse mistakes were made, largely out of a misplaced faith in the gold standard and balanced budgets. America’s tariffs were already high, and some other countries were already increasing their own. Nevertheless, the act added poison to the emptying well of global trade (see chart). The worldwide protection of the 1930s took decades to dismantle. And bad monetary and fiscal policies were at least based on the economic orthodoxy of the day: economists would tear each other apart over the heresies of John Maynard Keynes. On protection, there was no such division. More than a thousand
  • 11. economists petitioned Hoover not to sign the Smoot-Hawley bill. Bankers like Lamont sided with them; so did editorialists by the score. The “asinine” bill began as a much smaller beast: the plan was to help American agriculture, which had slumped in the early 1920s. Congress passed several bills to support prices and subsidise exports, but all were vetoed by Calvin Coolidge, Hoover’s predecessor. With no obvious logic—most American farmers faced little competition from imports—attention shifted to securing for agriculture the same sort of protection as for manufacturing, where tariffs were on average twice as high. To many of its supporters, “tariff equality” meant reducing industrial duties as well as raising those on farm goods. “But so soon as ever the tariff schedules were cast into the melting-pot of revision,” this newspaper wrote, “logrollers and politicians set to work stirring with all their might.” Start rolling In the 1928 election campaign Hoover and his fellow Republicans promised to revise the tariff. The Democrats, then the freer-trading party,
  • 12. were unusually acquiescent. After comfortable Republican wins in November, Hawley, the chairman of the House Ways and Means Committee, set to work. By the time Hoover was inaugurated in March 1929 and called a special session of Congress to tackle the tariff, his committee had gathered 43 days’, five nights’ and 11,000 pages’ worth of testimony. The door was open to more than just farmers; Hawley’s committee heard mainly from small and medium-sized industrial businesses. The House bill, passed in May, raised 845 tariff rates and cut 82. Douglas Irwin, an economist at Dartmouth and author of a forthcoming book (“The Battle over Protection: A History of US Trade Policy”) on which this article draws heavily, says it “tilted the tariff nearly as much toward higher duties on manufactured goods as it increased duties on agricultural imports.” The bill then went to the Senate, where Smoot chaired the Finance Committee. Senators who thought their constituents had lost out in the House—from farming and mining states—were spoiling for a fight. Smoot’s committee increased 177 rates from the House version and cut 254. In the next committee
  • 13. stage—which lasted from the autumn of 1929 until March 1930—the whole Senate could take part. Farming- and mining-state senators pruned Hawley’s increases in industrial tariffs. In the last Senate stage, senators from industrial states regrouped, fortified by the gathering economic gloom. “A different voting coalition emerged,” says Mr Irwin, “not one based on agricultural versus industrial interests but on classic vote-trading among unrelated goods.” Some senators disapproved: Robert LaFollette, a Republican from Wisconsin, called the bill “the product of a series of deals, conceived in secret, but executed in public with a brazen effrontery that is without parallel in the annals of the Senate.” Others saw nothing wrong. Charles Waterman, a Republican from Colorado, declared: “I have stated…that, by the eternal, I will not vote for a tariff upon the products of another state if the senators from that state vote against protecting the industries of my state.” The tariff’s critics—including Franklin Roosevelt, in his presidential campaign in 1932—dubbed the bill the “Grundy tariff”, after Joseph
  • 14. Grundy, a Republican senator from Pennsylvania and president of the Pennsylvania Manufacturers’ Association. Grundy had said that anyone who made campaign contributions was entitled to higher tariffs in return. The Senate’s final bill contained no fewer than 1,253 changes from the House’s version. The two houses compromised, broadly by moving the Senate’s rates up rather than the House’s down. In all, 890 tariffs were increased, compared with the previous Tariff Act, of 1922, which had itself raised duties dramatically (for examples, see table); 235 were cut. The bill squeezed through the Senate, by 44 votes to 42, and breezed through the House. Of all the calls on Hoover not to sign the bill, perhaps the weightiest was a petition signed by 1,028 American economists. A dozen years later Frank Fetter, one of the organisers, recalled their unanimity. “Economic faculties that within a few years were to be split wide open on monetary policy, deficit finance, and the problem of big business, were practically at one in their belief that the Hawley-Smoot bill was an iniquitous piece of legislation.”
  • 15. Some of the names are familiar even now. One was Frank Taussig, a former head of the Tariff Commission (which advised on whether duties should be raised or lowered). Another was Paul Douglas, later a senator (undergraduates are still introduced to the Cobb-Douglas production function). And a third was Irving Fisher. Fisher is still a giant of economics, best known for his work on monetary theory and index numbers. (He was fallible, though. Shortly before the 1929 stockmarket crash, he declared, “Stock prices have reached what looks like a permanently high plateau.”) According to Fetter, Fisher suggested that the petition refer explicitly to the importance of trade to America as a huge creditor nation: if other countries could not sell to the United States, how could they repay their debts? It was also thanks to Fisher that so many economists signed it. He proposed that it be sent to the entire membership of the American Economic Association, rather than to one member of each university’s faculty, and offered to meet the extra expense. The total cost was $137, of which Fisher paid $105.
  • 16. Expensive ink Hoover’s signature cost rather more—even though the direct effect on American trade was limited. The average rate on dutiable goods rose from 40% to 48%, implying a price increase of only 6%. And most trade, Mr Irwin points out, was free of duty (partly because high tariffs discouraged imports). He estimates that the new tariff reduced dutiable imports by 17-20% and the total by 4-6%. Yet the volume of American imports had already dropped by 15% in the year before the act was passed. It would fall by a further 40% in a little more than two years. Other, bigger forces were at work. Chief among these was the fall in American GDP, the causes of which went far beyond protection. The other was deflation, which amplified the effects of the existing tariff and the Smoot- Hawley increases. In those days most tariffs were levied on the volume of imports (so many cents per pound, say) rather than value. So as deflation took hold after 1929, effective tariff rates climbed, discouraging imports. By 1932, the average American tariff on dutiable imports was 59.1%; only once before, in 1830, had it been higher. Mr Irwin
  • 17. reckons that the Tariff Act raised duties by 20%; deflation accounted for half as much again. Smoot-Hawley did most harm by souring trade relations with other countries. The League of Nations, of which America was not a member, had talked of a “tariff truce”; the Tariff Act helped to undermine that idea. By September 1929 the Hoover administration had already noted protests from 23 trading partners at the prospect of higher tariffs. But the threat of retaliation was ignored: America’s tariffs were America’s business. The Congressional Record, notes Mr Irwin, contains 20 pages of debate on the duty on tomatoes but very little on the reaction from abroad. A study by Judith McDonald, Anthony Patrick O’Brien and Colleen Callahan* examines the response of Canada, America’s biggest trading partner. When Hoover was elected president, the Canadian prime minister, Mackenzie King, wrote in his diary that his victory would lead to “border warfare”. King, who had cut tariffs in the early 1920s, warned the Americans that retaliation might follow. In May 1930,
  • 18. with higher American tariffs all but certain, he imposed extra duties on some American goods—and cut tariffs on imports from the rest of the British empire. He promptly called a general election, believing he had done enough to satisfy Canadians’ resentment. America, wrote the New York Times, was “consciously giving Canada inducements to turn to England for the goods which she has been buying from the United States.” Canadians agreed. King’s Liberals were crushed by the Conservatives, who favoured and enacted even higher tariffs. All this, of course, is history. There are plenty of reasons to think that the terrible lesson of the 1930s will not have to be learnt again. Governments have reaffirmed their commitment to open trade and the World Trade Organisation (WTO). The http://www.economist.com/finance/displaystory.cfm?story_id=1 2798595#footnote1 complex patterns of cross-border commerce, with myriad stages of production spread over so many countries, would be enormously costly to pull apart. And yet. Tariffs can be increased, even under the WTO. The use
  • 19. of anti-dumping is on the rise. Favours offered to one industry (farming then; cars now?) can be hard to refuse to others. And the fact that politicians know something to be madness does not stop them doing it. They were told in 1930: 1,028 times over. The world economy The return of economic nationalism Feb 5th 2009 From The Economist print edition A spectre is rising. To bury it again, Barack Obama needs to take the lead Illustration by Jon Berkeley MANAGING a crisis as complex as this one has so far called for nuance and pragmatism rather than stridency and principle. Should governments prop up credit markets by offering guarantees or creating bad banks? Probably both. What package
  • 20. of fiscal stimulus would be most effective? It varies from one country to the next. Should banks be nationalised? Yes, in some circumstances. Only the foolish and the partisan have rejected (or embraced) any solutions categorically. But the re-emergence of a spectre from the darkest period of modern history argues for a different, indeed strident, response. Economic nationalism—the urge to keep jobs and capital at home—is both turning the economic crisis into a political one and threatening the world with depression. If it is not buried again forthwith, the consequences will be dire. Devil take the hindmost Trade encourages specialisation, which brings prosperity; global capital markets, for all their problems, allocate money more efficiently than local ones; economic co-operation encourages confidence and enhances security. Yet despite its obvious benefits, the globalised economy is under threat. Congress is arguing about a clause in the $800 billion-plus stimulus package that in its most extreme form would press for the use of American materials in
  • 21. public works. Earlier, Tim Geithner, the new treasury secretary, accused China of “manipulating” its currency, prompting snarls from Beijing. Around the world, carmakers have lobbied for support (see article), and some have got it. A host of industries, in countries from India to Ecuador, want help from their governments. The grip of nationalism is tightest in banking (see article). In France and Britain, politicians pouring taxpayers’ money into ailing banks are demanding that the cash be lent at home. Since banks are reducing overall lending, that means repatriating cash. Regulators are thinking nationally too. Switzerland now favours domestic loans by ignoring them in one measure of the capital its banks need to hold; foreign loans count in full. Governments protect goods and capital largely in order to protect jobs. Around the world, workers are demanding help from the state with increasing panic. British strikers, quoting Gordon Brown’s ill-chosen words back at him, are demanding that he provide “British jobs
  • 22. for British workers” (see article). In France more than 1m people stayed away from work on January 29th, marching for jobs and wages. In Greece police used tear gas to control farmers calling for even more subsidies. Three arguments are raised in defence of economic nationalism: that it is justified commercially; that it is justified politically; and that it won’t get very far. On the first point, some damaged banks may feel safer retreating to their home markets, where they understand the risks and benefit from scale; but that is a trend which governments should seek to counteract, not to encourage. On the second point, it is reasonable for politicians to want to spend taxpayers’ money at home—so long as the costs of doing so are not unacceptably high. In this case, however, the costs could be enormous. For the third argument—that protectionism will not get very far—is dangerously complacent. True, everybody sensible scoffs at Reed Smoot and Willis Hawley, the lawmakers who in 1930 exacerbated the
  • 23. Depression by raising American tariffs. But reasonable people opposed them at the time, and failed to stop them: 1,028 economists petitioned against their bill. Certainly, global supply-chains are more complex and harder to pick apart than in those days. But when nationalism is on the march, even commercial logic gets trampled underfoot. The links that bind countries’ economies together are under strain. World trade may well shrink this year for the first time since 1982. Net private-sector capital flows to the emerging markets are likely to fall to $165 billion, from a peak of $929 billion in 2007. Even if there were no policies to undermine it, globalisation is suffering its biggest reversal in the modern era. Politicians know that, with support for open markets low and falling, they must be seen to do something; and policies designed to put something right at home can inadvertently eat away at the global system. An attempt to prop up Ireland’s banks last year sucked deposits out of Britain’s. American plans to monitor domestic bank lending month by month will
  • 24. encourage lending at home rather than abroad. As countries try to save themselves they endanger each other. The big question is what America will do. At some moments in this crisis it has shown the way—by agreeing to supply dollars to countries that needed them, and by guaranteeing the contracts of European banks when it rescued a big insurer. But the “Buy American” provisions in the stimulus bill are alarmingly nationalistic. They would not even boost American employment in the short run, because—just as with Smoot-Hawley—the inevitable retaliation would destroy more jobs at exporting firms. And the political consequences would http://www.economist.com/opinion/displaystory.cfm?story_id=1 3057275 http://www.economist.com/opinion/displaystory.cfm?story_id=1 3057265 http://www.economist.com/opinion/displaystory.cfm?story_id=1 3061705 be far worse than the economic ones. They would send a disastrous signal to the rest of the world: the champion of open markets is going it alone. A time to act
  • 25. Barack Obama says that he doesn’t like “Buy American” (and the provisions have been softened in the Senate’s version of the stimulus plan). That’s good—but not enough. Mr Obama should veto the entire package unless they are removed. And he must go further, by championing three principles. The first principle is co-ordination—especially in rescue packages, like the one that helped the rich world’s banks last year. Countries’ stimulus plans should be built around common principles, even if they differ in the details. Co-ordination is good economics, as well as good politics: combined plans are also more economically potent than national ones. The second principle is forbearance. Each nation’s stimulus plan should embrace open markets, even if some foreigners will benefit. Similarly, financial regulators should leave the re-regulation of cross-border banking until later, at an international level, rather than beggaring their neighbours by grabbing scarce capital, setting targets for domestic lending and drawing up rules with long-term consequences now.
  • 26. The third principle is multilateralism. The IMF and the development banks should help to meet emerging markets’ shortfall in capital. They need the structure and the resources to do so. The World Trade Organisation can help to shore up the trading system if its members pledge to complete the Doha round of trade talks and make good on their promise at last year’s G20 meeting to put aside the arsenal of trade sanctions. When economic conflict seems more likely than ever, what can persuade countries to give up their trade weapons? American leadership is the only chance. The international economic system depends upon a guarantor, prepared to back it during crises. In the 19th century Britain played that part. Nobody did between the wars, and the consequences were disastrous. Partly because of that mistake, America bravely sponsored a new economic order after the second world war. Once again, the task of saving the world economy falls to America. Mr Obama must show that he is ready for it. If he is, he should kill any “Buy American” provisions. If he isn’t, America and the rest of the world are in deep trouble.