SlideShare a Scribd company logo
1 of 47
1
The Euro Zone Crisis,
 Its dimensions and
Implications
by
J.K.Nanda
Kini Nagendra
ITM –Vashi
XMBA-21
2
Content
Page No
Abstract 03
Introduction 04
The Euro Zone: A background 05
Creation of the Euro: its Justification 06
Convergence, cohabitation and divergence 06
From the global crisis to the Euro zone crisis 11
The rescue: creation of the EFSF and the ESM 13
Some critical dimensions of the EZC 17
A monetary union without a fiscal union
Structural differences

 Cross border lending

 Decision making in the Euro zone
Implications and Possible directions 22
Implications for the advanced countries:
Euro zone crisis and the EMEs
 Possible directions
Concluding observations 27
References
 28
Annex tables
 29
Endnotes 33
FAQs 34
Abstract:
3
The sovereign debt problems in the peripheral economies of the euro
zone has started to pose a serious threat to the main economies of the
Europe and perhaps to the future of the ̳euro‘ itself. Such a situation is a
far cry from the optimism and grand vision that marked its launch. This
paper is an attempt to understand the implications of the ongoing euro
zone crisis and the factors that make it somewhat unique as the
contradictions of a monetary union without a fiscal union are coming to
fore. The paper shows that the crisis is not merely related to sovereign
debt and bank financials but also rooted in the real economy with
structural problems. The manner in which the crisis is dealt is likely to be
of far reaching significance to Europe and to the rest of the world. The
stage seems set for a change in the way in which the euro zone will need
to manage its monetary, fiscal and financial system.
The Euro Zone Crisis

4
Its dimensions and implications
Over the last two years, the euro zone has been going through an agonizing debate
over the handling of its own home grown crisis, now the ̳euro zone crisis‘. Starting
from Greece, Ireland, Portugal, Spain and more recently Italy, these euro zone
economies have witnessed a downgrade of the rating of their sovereign debt, fears
of default and a dramatic rise in borrowing costs. These developments threaten
other Euro zone economies and even the future of the Euro.
Such a situation is a far cry from the optimism and grand vision that marked the
launch of the Euro in 1999 and the relatively smooth passage it enjoyed thereafter.
While the Euro zone may be forced to do what it takes, it is unlikely that the
situation will soon return to business as usual on its own. Yet, this crisis is not a
currency crisis in a classic sense. Rather, it is about managing economies in a
currency zone and the economic and political tensions that arise from the fact that
its constituents are moving at varying speeds, have dramatically different fiscal
capacities and debt profiles but their feet are tied together with a single currency.
Given the large economic weight of the euro zone in the globe, and regularity with
which the crisis is spreading from one euro zone economy to the next, the stage for
palliatives is over. The manner, in which the euro zone crisis is dealt this point
onwards, is likely to be of far reaching significance to the world. This paper shows
that the crisis is not merely of sovereign debt and bank financials but also rooted in
the real economy with structural problems. The stage is set for a change in the
manner in which the euro zone will have to manage its monetary, fiscal and
financial system.
This paper is an attempt to understand the implications of the euro zone crisis in the
light of the developments subsequent to the creation of the euro. Starting with a
background in section 2, the paper analyses the factors that make the euro zone
crisis unique in section 3. Section 4 delineates the significance of the ongoing
developments which is followed by a few concluding observations.
5
Section 2
 :
The Euro Zone: A background
On January 1, 1999 eleven European countries decided to denominate
their currencies into a single currency. The European monetary union
(EMU) was conceived earlier in 1988–89 by a committee consisting
mainly of central bankers which led to the Maastricht Treaty in 1991.
The treaty established budgetary and monetary rules for countries
wishing to join the EMU - called the ―convergence criteria‖i. The
criterion were designed to be a basis for qualifying for the EMU and
pertained to the size of budget deficits, national debt, inflation, interest
rates, and exchange rates. Denmark, Sweden, and the United Kingdom
chose not to join from the inception.
Figure 1. The Euro Zone, Source ECB
The "Euro system" comprised the European Central Bank (ECB), with
11 central banks of participating States assuming the responsibility for
monetary policy. A large part of Europe came to have the same currency
much like the Roman Empire, but with a crucial difference. The
members were sovereign countries with their own tax systems. Greece
failed to qualify, but was later admitted on 1 January 2001. The ̳Euro‘
6
took the form of notes and coins in 2002, and replaced the domestic
currencies. From eleven euro zone members in 1999, the number
increased to 17 in 2011.
Justification for the Euro: The overarching justification for the Euro was
not merely economic, but political. A single currency was perceived as a
symbol of political and social integration in the post WW II Europe and
a catalyst for further integration in other spheres. At the micro level, the
use of a common currency was expected to increase cross- border
competition, integration and efficiency in the markets for goods, services
and capital. These developments were expected to reduce transactions
costs (Hämäläinen:1999). The underlying logic for economies to
integrate and adopt a single currency was based largely on the Theory of
Optimum Currency Areas (OCA)‘, pioneered in the seminal work of
Robert Mundell (1961).
At the macroeconomic level, a single monetary policy in the euro area
was expected to be geared to price stability. According to the ECB, the
monetary policy in the Euro system has been guided by two ―pillars‖.
First, an inflation target broadly based on an assessment of future price
developments and the risks to price stability in the euro area measured by
the Harmonized Index of Consumer Prices (HICP) and second, a
―reference value‖— not a specific monetary target— for the growth of a
broad monetary aggregate.
The Euro system's commitment to price stability was expected to
contribute to the long- term stability and credibility of the euro and
promote its attractiveness as a trading and investment currency. In the
long run, the development and integration of the euro area financial
markets was expected to enhance the attractiveness of the euro. The Euro
was also expected to become an important currency in the foreign
exchange markets.
Convergence, cohabitation and divergence: Since the euro came into
existence in 1999, and later in the physical form in 2002, there remained
some skepticism on its future as some members had failed to stay within
the norms under the growth and stability pact. Nevertheless, the euro
7
area money and financial markets saw rapid changes with the
introduction of a new currency. Bond markets that were segmented got
integrated in short period. From 1999 to 2002, and then on, there was
convergence in the yields on government bonds (figure 2a). Interest rate
dispersion between the rates offered by different banks in also declined
(Figure 2b). The dispersion of country short-term rates measured also
reduced.
Figure 2a
Source: OECD data
8
Figure 2b
Source: Eurostat data
Increased competition, the establishment of common benchmarks and
lower transaction costs led to narrowing of yield and spreads and market
liquidity across borders. These changes were facilitated by the TARGETiv
system that linked large-value national payments in the EU. Thus similar
instruments traded in the different national markets came to be perceived
as close substitutes.
The convergence in interest rates meant a fall in nominal rates in the
peripheral economies towards the lower German levels (figure-2a).
Credibility of the monetary policy on price stability and the
accompanying economic growth were seen as positive outcomes of a
single market and a seemingly stable common currency.
Credit growth surged as currency risk premium diminished and
competition spurred financial innovations as financial institutions could
borrow easily abroad (figure 3a). The growth in credit was concentrated
in the housing sector. Construction and financial services grew rapidly
thereby increasing macroeconomic vulnerability. While property prices
boomed (figure 3b), the credit growth got translated into a buildup in
debt.
9
Figure 3a,
Source: IMF, IFS data
Figure 3b
Source: FT. com
Faster growth hid the weakness in the fiscal system that got revealed
with the worsening in the fiscal deficit and public debt (Annex table).
Growth was also accompanied by a rise in demand for imports and, in
turn, a larger current account deficit from 2003. The rise in the twin
deficits (figure-4a and 4b) were financed largely through debt,
especially, in the case of Greece. So long as growth was strong, it was
hard to make out whether there had been an improvement in the
fundamentals, or it was a bubble. Till 2005, the general growth
10
momentum was in place, perhaps waiting for a trigger.
Figure 4a
Source: Eurostat
Figure 4b
Source; Eurostat
11
Section 3
 :
From Global crisis to the Euro zone crisis
The global financial crisis in 2007–08 acted as the trigger that set the
snow ball of debt rolling across Europe and in the euro zone as growth
declined sharply (figure 5). The financial crisis led to disruption in
financial intermediation. The credit boom from 2003 lasting till early
2007 was supported by falling interest rates. But from 2006, interest
rates across euro zone started to diverge, marking out the weak from the
strong economies (as shown in figure 2a). Excessive lending had left
banks with bad debts and governments with large fiscal deficit and
public debt in the peripheral economies (albeit of varying magnitudes).
12
Figure 5
Source: Eurostat
In order to meet liquidity problem arising from financial crisis, on 11
October 2008, the EU held an extraordinary summit in Paris to define a
joint action for the euro zone and agreed to a bank rescue plan to boost
their finances and guarantee interbank lending. Coordination against the
crisis was considered vital to prevent the actions of one country harming
another and exacerbating bank solvency and credit shortage.
The various emergency measures announced to counter financial crisis
during 2008- 2009, appeared to have been successful in averting
financial crisis and supporting short- term domestic demand. However,
they aggravated fiscal deficit and debt. In late 2009, Greece admitted that
its fiscal deficit was understated (12.7 % of GDP, as against 3.7 % stated
earlier). Ratings agencies downgraded Greek bank and government debt.
In late 2009, its public debt was over 113 % of GDP, far more that the
euro zone limit of 60 %.
A crisis of confidence due to high fiscal deficit and debt was marked by
widening bond yields and risk insurance on credit default swaps. By
early 2010, a sovereign debt crisis in the euro zone was clearly on hand
with Greece in the eye of the storm. The problems of Ireland, Portugal
and Spain were also out in the open. Even though, the configuration of
fiscal deficit, public debt, private debt and bank lending across these
13
economies was considerably different, the financial markets passed a
similar judgment through a rise in the CDS premiums, albeit
differentiated (figure 6). After all, the global financial crisis had brought
home an important lesson - that on the extreme, all private debt could
potentially be public debt.
Source: Datastream
On 2 May 2010, to reassure investors confidence, the EU and IMF put
together a €110bn bailout package for Greece conditional on
implementation of austerity measures. This was followed on 9 May 2010
by a decision by 27 member states of the European Union to create the
European Financial Stability Facility (EFSF), a special purpose vehicle,
in order to help preserve financial stability in Europe by providing
financial assistance to euro zone states in difficulty. The EFSF was
empowered to sell bonds and use the money to make loans up to a
maximum of € 440 billion to euro zone nations. The bonds were to be
backed by guarantees given by the European Commission representing
the whole EU, the euro zone member states, and the IMF. The EFSF
combined the € 60 billion loan coming from the European financial
stabilization mechanism (reliant on guarantees given by the European
Commission using the EU budget as collateral) and a € 250 billion loan
backed by the IMF in order to obtain a financial safety net up to € 750
billion. The agreement allowed the ECB to start buying government debt
which was expected to reduce bond yields. As per the conditions, Greece
14
was to mobilize $ 70 billion by way of privatization of its state
enterprises. In November, 2010 EU and IMF agree to bail-out the Irish
Republic with 85bn Euros. The Irish Republic soon passes the toughest
budget in the country's history.
The measures taken in May 2010 had a palliative effect. Serious doubts
remained on the ability of Greece to service its debt and bond yields
started to spike again. In April 2011, Portugal admitted that it could not
deal with its finances and asked the EU for help. In May 2011, European
finance ministers approved euro 78 billion rescue loans to Portugal.
Meanwhile, Moody‘s lowered Greece‘s credit rating to junk status on
June 1 2011 (to Caa1 from B1).
An extraordinary summit was again convened on 21 July 2011 in
Brussels. The leaders decided to take measures to stop the risk of
contagion. They agreed on a further bailout for Greece for 109billion
euros with the participation of the IMF and voluntary contribution from
the private sector in order to cover the financing gap. The EFSF was
indicated as the financing vehicle for the disbursement with regular
assessment by the Commission in liaison with the ECB and the IMF.
The agreement included extending the loan repayment periods and a cut
in interest rates. To prevent the possible contagion, the leaders agreed to
increase the flexibility of the EFSF to be able to lend to states
preventively on the basis of a precautionary programme. The EFSF was
empowered to recapitalize financial institutions through loans to
governments even in those countries that were not under any
programme. Further the EFSF was allowed to intervene in the secondary
markets to deal with exceptional financial market circumstances and in
the event of a risk to financial stability.
To increase fiscal consolidation and growth in the euro area, the 17
leaders pledged continued support to the countries successfully
implementing their programmes. They agreed to apply to Portugal and
Ireland the same EFSF lending conditions that they confirmed for
Greece, i.e., extended debt maturities to a minimum of 15 years and
reduced interest rate to around 3.5 %. It was agreed that all the euro area
15
member states would strictly adhere to the agreed fiscal targets. In
addition to solving their eventual macro-economic imbalances, the
member states (with the exception of those under a programme) are to
reduce their deficits below 3 percent by 2013. As an additional measure,
the leaders invited the European Investment Bank to help the countries
receiving EU and IMF assistance in absorbing the funds.
All these measures have so far failed to assuage the financial markets.
The indications are that the financial markets continue to be deeply
skeptical about their effectiveness. While Greece remains an extreme
case, the problem of public and private debt (in varying proportions) in
other peripheral economies like Ireland, Portugal, Spain and Italy are
also a source of concern albeit with their own peculiarities. We recount
some of the specificities of the problem faced in these economies before
reverting to the overarching dimensions and implications of the euro
zone crisis.
Ireland: The case of Ireland has been marked by an almost whole sale
nationalization of the banking sector that translated into severe fiscal
stress. But not long back, the Ireland was hailed as the Celtic tiger for its
economic dynamism. The economy expanded rapidly during 1997-2007
with investment stimulated, in part, due to a low corporate tax rates.
With low interest rates, there was rapid expansion of credit and property
valuations from 2002 to 2007. The rise in mortgages was accompanied
by banks relying heavily on whole sale external borrowing. As property
prices showed a downward movement from 2007 Irish banks stood
exposed and came under severe pressure. The property price crash by the
first half of 2009 broadly coincided with the tightening of credit control.
By mid April 09, there was a marked increase in Irish bond yields and
the government had to nationalize banks and take on the liabilitiesvi. In
September 2010, government support for six banks had risen markedly
to 32 per cent of GDP. In November 2010, the government decided to
seek a €85 billion "bailout" from the ECB and the IMF. Thus the
problems of Ireland stemmed from an excessive build up of bank lending
rather than public debt as in the case of Greece. But, the banking crisis
turned into a fiscal problem. In terms of unemployment, Ireland with an
16
unemployment rate of 13.7 percent is among the worst-affected, after
Spain which also witnessed a collapse in the property sector.
Spain, like Ireland, was considered a dynamic economy and till 2005 and
attracted significant foreign investment. The economy witnessed a real
estate boom with construction representing close to 16 per cent of GDP.
This changed with the global crisis. In cumulative terms, housing prices
fell significantly from 2007. As the real estate boom collapsed there was
a rise in the levels of personal debt. On the public finances front, tax
revenues collapsed, deficits soared and the budget position moved to a
deficit of over 11 per cent in 2009 (Annex tables). Interest rates on
lending to companies and other categories showed an upward turn and
financing continued to decline indicating weakness of the economy.
The one difference that marks out Spain is that its public debt at about 60
per cent of GDP (in 2010) is low by euro zone standards. But the
problem is on account of foreign exposure to its private debt. The
Spanish banks have relied heavily on whole sale finance from abroad.
Spain also has a very high rate of unemployment in comparison to the
rest of the euro zone. Unemployment among youth is particularly high in
Spain and remains a potential source of unrest.
Portugal: While the Financial Crisis affected the Portuguese economy on
account of which its fiscal deficit and public debt deteriorated from -3.1
per cent and 68 per cent of GDP (in 2007) to -10 per cent and 83 percent
in 2009, the down turn in GDP growth for Portugal was one of the
mildest (only -2.5 %) compared to a sharper decline in the rest of the
euro zone. Public debt and deficit is also lower than Greece. In that
respect, the situation of Portugal is unlike the other peripheral economies
that witnessed a boom-bust situation. Portugal, however, has a
significantly large external current account deficit and external debt
fuelled largely by private sector borrowing.
In terms of other social indicators that are critical for productivity,
Portugal ranks low. For instance, as per the OECD surveys, Portugal has
one of the lowest percentage of population with at least upper secondary
education in the age group of 25 to 64 as compared to the EU average.
17
Alongside, Portugal has also shown an increase in the structural rate of
unemployment right from 2000. In other words, Portugal faces a
somewhat different problem from some of the other peripheral
economies, that is - of chronic low rate of growth.
Italy: Italy is the eighth-largest economy in the world and the fourth-
largest in Europe in terms of nominal GDP (in 2010). It has been a slow
growth economy with GDP growth averaging just about 1 per cent per
annum over 2000-07 as compared to close to 2 per cent for the euro
zone. While its fiscal deficit at -4.6 per cent of GDP in 2010 is lower
than the - 6 per cent for the euro zone, Italy‘s public debt and external
debt ratios at 119 and 108 are rather large. Even though much of the
public debt is held by its residents, it has large private tradable debt
which makes it very difficult to rescue. While its unemployment rate at
8.4 per cent is lower than the average for the euro zone, Italy has always
been characterized by north- south divide with the southern parts
witnessing chronically high unemployment rates.
An point to note is that there are significant differences in terms of the
configuration of macroeconomic variables and structural differences (an
aspect we discuss in the next section) across the euro zone economies
that are currently in trouble. In Greece, the banks – which were
reasonably strong on a ―stand-alone‖ basis were undone by revelations
about the weakness of public finances. In Ireland, causation ran in an
opposite direction with failing domestic banks imposing a burden on the
fiscal position. Regardless of the causation, the consequences have been
the same: as confidence eroded, the inflow of foreign capital dried up
and public debt mounted. Nevertheless, the markets have been
penalizing one economy after another, albeit to different degrees. And
the contagion effect seems to be spreading. Are there some dimensions
that make the euro zone crisis special? We turn to this question in the
next section.
Section 4
 :
Some critical dimensions of the EZ crisis
18
By 2011, the euro zone crisis turned predominantly into a sovereign debt
crisis intricately woven with bank debt and claims across borders within
and outside the monetary union. In that respect, the euro zone problem is
somewhat unique and sui generisvii.
A monetary union without a fiscal union: The creation of the Euro zone
had an inherent contradiction of being a monetary union but not a fiscal
union. The introduction of the euro in 1999 explicitly prevented the ECB
or any national central bank from financing government deficits. As a
consequence the central bank has no power to monetize deficits.
The above arrangement put a premium on each country to follow a
similar fiscal path, but, without a common treasury to enforce it. The
spending authorities remained national and subject to their own political
compulsions. So long as growth across the region was strong, the fiscal
capacity was not a source of worry. In such an arrangement the
possibility of fiscal free riding is present as seen from the current episode
for Greece. Given the differences in the structure and competitiveness of
the peripheral economies, it is not surprising that their compliance to the
growth and stability pact was often in breach. And this weakness got
further exposed in the after math of the global crisis due to the operation
of fiscal stabilizers, a rise in the unemployment compensation and a fall
in tax revenues. The option of improving the competiveness of the
economy through exchange rate depreciation was not available from the
very inception of the monetary union. The EU budget is only 1 % of the
EU GDP and not an effective instrument for fiscal stabilization. Had
there been a fiscal union, with a system horizontal transfer and controls,
the deficit and debt ratio of the peripheral economies may have been
contained. But in the present case, a fiscal crisis in the periphery
automatically translated into zonal monetary and financial crisis with the
central monetary authority not empowered to act as the lender of last
resort.
This brings home an important lesson that setting up pacts and codes of
conduct by themselves are not enough, unless, the underlying incentives
19
to adhere to them are also reasonably well aligned. It has also been
argued that the fiscal criteria proved difficult to enforce but generated a
false assurance that as long as there was a criteria, all was well. They
failed to see that other structural problems were far more dangerous to
economic stability of the euro zone that included the lack of control and
regulation over national financial institutions (Pavoncello: 2011).
Varying productivity and Structural differences: Within the euro zone,
there is substantial variation in terms of productivity. The peripheral
economies have lower labor productivity compared to Germany (taken
as a bench mark of 100) which clearly stands out in terms of unit labour
costs. Only France and Ireland are comparable to Germany on this count
(figure 7a).
Figure 7a
Source: OECD
The Global competitiveness index for the Euro zone countries also
shows vast differences in terms of the ranking and score (annex table).
On account of differences in the labor market conditions the
unemployment rates are also vast divergent. As compared to the
peripheral economies, Germany has the lowest rate of unemployment
rate due to its short-time working scheme and flexible time arrangements
in the manufacturing sector (Annex table and figure 6b). The fact that
there has been a persistence different in the unemployment levels show
20
that labour mobility remained far more limited as compared capital
mobility despite there being a monetary union.
Figure 7b
Source Eurostat
The above differences in a currency union could get sharply exaggerated,
as they did, when countries are subject to asymmetric shocks, or to put it
the other way around, when their capacity to weather a similar shock is
vastly different. Member countries cannot use the exchange rate
adjustment to improve their competitiveness. Large fiscal deficit and
public debt with interconnected and weak banking systems can then
make matters worse if debt is held across borders which is an issue we
deal with shortly. In the peripheral economies of the euro zone all these
problems seem to have occurred in quick succession.
21
Role of cross border lending:
The modest success of the euro had all along been crucially dependent
on the ability of the constituent economies to maintain, or appear to
maintain,
 fiscal discipline and the ability of
 the private sector and the
financial
 services industry to retain the trust
 of the markets. Ironically,
it is the integration in the financial and money markets, that in part, was
due to a common currency, which makes the euro zone crisis harder to
untangle.
This foregoing integration is seen in terms of the large share of public
debt held across borders (table 1) with European banks (German, French,
British and others) having cross border exposure. Data from the Bank of
International settlements gives an indication of the magnitude of
exposure for major economies in the euro zone. Germany and France
non euro economies like UK and US have substantial exposure to bank
debt of the peripheral economies (Table 2). In respect of the US, the
indirect exposure is several times larger than the direct exposure. The
interlocking and conflicting interests of the holders of the liabilities of
the peripheral euro zone economies thorough cross border holding of
debt makes the resolution of the euro zone crisis furthermore difficult.
Aggregate data, needs to be interpreted with caution, as the magnitude is
not a direct indicator of the potential default, but only of the total
exposure at a point in time, that too with incomplete coverage.
22
Nevertheless, given their large exposure, the European banks may find it
difficult to wish away their engagement with the peripheral economies.
Decision making system in
 the Euro zone: Even at the
 national level
where there are
 sub national entities, decision
 making is always
problematic.
 In the case of the Euro zone
 decisions on financial

assistance requires unanimity
 among representatives of
 member
states. In a monetary
 union, political decisions taken
 in one country
affect the
 economies of other countries. Except for the ECB there are
few organizations’ that have a euro zone wide view. But the ECB is a
central bank with a limited focus on the macro- economy. But economic
policies remain controlled by national governments with fiscal
consequence.
23
Section 5
 :
Implications of the EZC and possible directions
The euro zone crisis has been moving from one peripheral economy to
the next, and more recently, is affecting the core economies in the euro
zone. The EU accounts for close to 26 per cent of the world GDP (at
market exchange rates) and the euro zone 19.4 per cent. The Euro area
accounts for about 10 per cent of the global equity markets turnover and
the euro accounts for 26 percent of the allocated global holding of
reserves. Thus the significance of this crisis is not merely that it comes in
the aftermath of the global crisis, but more importantly, it threatens the
pace of recovery of the global economy especially because the EU and
within that, the Euro zone is a significant market for rest of the world.
In its "spillover" report on the effects of euro zone policies on other
major economies, the IMF observed that an intensification of the euro
area debt crisis, especially if stress were to spread to the core economies
could have major global consequences. In particular, if the Euro area
core economies were to be affected. Banks throughout the euro zone
immediately require more and higher quality capital. While capital
raising and recapitalizing banks is needed, the report observes that in the
short run, this may have a contractionary effect. But the critical question
that arises in this context is where the resources for recapitalizing the
banks will come from?
Implications for the advanced countries: More than any part of the world,
the manner in which the current crisis is dealt is important for the Euro
zone and to Europe. The creation of the European Union and the euro
zone has been part of the European dream of integration.
A breakup of the euro would be painful in economic terms and in terms
of its political fallout.
A serious challenge is being faced by the two European giants Germany
and France because the banks of both these countries face large
24
exposures as already indicated. The markets have been relentless in
pricing them down. Even the United Kingdom, that technically remains
outside the euro zone does not have the choice of remaining a passive
spectator for the same reason as British banks also have a substantial
exposure to debt in the troubled countries of the Euro zone.
As at present, the United States has a large financial stake in Europe.
American banks have over $600 billion of exposure in the troubled
economies of the euro zone as per BIS data. There are close trading links
as Europe is US’s largest trading partner and the largest destination for
investment by U.S. corporations.
Following the collapse of the Lehman brothers in 2008, the US opened
short term loans to European banks. In 2009, the US Fed went in for the
second round of quantitative easing by buying treasury bonds and
pushing down long-term interest rates. By August 2011, its own debt
position has become a matter of concern. The capacity of US to
accommodate liquidity in order to support the euro zone economies, this
time around may be more limited.
The Euro zone crisis and the EMEs: The current crisis is important in
terms of the current transition that is taking place globally in the geo
political context. For both China and India, Europe and the euro zone
accounts for a significant market. Therefore stagnation or worse, a
downturn in the euro zone will dent their export growth.
But in regard to China, the threats and the opportunities are somewhat
interestingly balanced. China has been looking for opportunities to
diversify its foreign exchange assets. The current situation provides
China an opportunity to make bargains during a fire sale that may follow
to gain political mileage and acquire useful and perhaps strategic assets
by simply offering to hold troubled assets of the troubled euro zone
States. These assets could be in the form of sovereign debt as well as real
assets like interest in public sector units that may be privatized. The
manner in which the euro zone and the EU would respond to this
possibility remains to be seen.
25
As far as India is concerned, the European Union is a major trade partner
accounting for as much as 20.2 per cent of India’s exports (in 2009-10)
and 13.3 per cent of India’s imports. European Union countries imported
roughly € 33.1 billion worth of Agriculture products, Fuel and mining
products, machinery and transport equipment, chemicals, semi
manufactured products textile and clothing products in 2010 from India.
The EU exports to India amounted to €34.8bl, majority of which was
machinery, chemical products and semi manufactured items which was
almost 2.6 percent of EU exports. Bilateral trade between the two has
been growing on an average of 9.6 per cent during 2006-10. EU services
exports to India during 2010 was €9.8 billion and EU imports from India
was €8.1 billion. That apart, the total FDI from EU during 2010
amounted to €3.0 billion while India also invested about €0.6 billion in
the EU. In other words, a slowdown in the euro zone and the EU is likely
to have a major adverse impact on India’s exports.
Apart from trade, the euro zone experience has some lessons for India.
Whole sale debt funding has been the unmaking for banks in the Euro
zone. While it is difficult to argue that banks should only raise debt
resources through retail deposits, at the same time, the current episode
shows that large scale reliance on whole sale debt, especially, from
across borders may not be in the interest of financial stability. In this
context, the Indian banking system has traditionally relied on retail
deposits which despite higher cost; serve as a stable source of funding.
Without necessarily shunning the option, any substantial shift towards
whole sale debt funding may not be a desirable.
India, despite its high fiscal deficit and debt has the advantage of public
debt being passively held in bank portfolios. This practice has continued
hitherto as a vestige of the era of financial repression. While there is
every reason to maintain prudence in public finance, at a given point, this
EZ experience raises the question of whether sovereign debt of a country
can be held largely outside a country in portfolios that keep getting
churned and subject to day-to-day re-pricing. This issue is important
since sovereign debt, unlike corporate debt, is meant to finance long-
term development.
26
The global financial crisis demonstrated that the globalized banking
system played a crucial role in transmitting the crisis from the advanced
economies to various parts of the world, including the emerging markets.
The current crisis also bears lessons for making a choice on the manner
in which foreign banks operating in emerging economies should be
allowed by the regulators to expand, that is, through the route of
subsidiaries or through branches.
Possible directions: For dealing with the EZ crisis, the possible
alternatives being debated are on three broad lines. The first is the route
of austerity, in particular, fiscal consolidation, including privatization.
This is the default policy choice. A forgone conclusion is that this will
impose social costs. While fiscal consolidation is desirable, the question
is whether, at all, this choice will lead to sustained growth in the near
future, since the compression at this juncture would be extreme. Real
growth is stagnating and prospects of exports leading growth appear dim.
The peripheral economies are subject to a large mismatch between
revenues and expenditure at the level of the government and at the
household level leading to unsustainable governments and private debt.
The possibility that these economies will grow themselves out of the
problem seems remote. In any case, this choice does not address the
structural problems faced in the peripheral economies. Therefore, the
current strategy of announcing short term palliatives such as further bail
outs along with sharp fiscal consolidation may only prolong the agony
but not deal with the uncertainty prevailing in the euro zone.
The second option, (rather an imperative), would be to go in for a closer
fiscal union and a substantially enlarged European budget with a limited
system of fiscal transfers from rich countries to the poor countries, a
common form of protection for employment on the German lines with
more flexibility, greater cross border investment even if this implies
takeover of sick and ailing public sector units by companies from the
richer Euro zone states. A further step would then be to move the ECB
into the role of a proper central banker and then floating euro bonds.
27
EMES is a research network of established university research centres and individual researchers
whose goal is to gradually build up a European corpus of theoretical and empirical knowledge,
pluralistic in disciplines and methodology, around “Third Sector” issues.
A fiscal union, if that be the future road, between what are clearly a few
strong and other weaker economies is going to be a major political and
economic challenge. In light of the experience thus far, it may be
necessary to build an institutional framework that permits a multi speed
Europe rather than hoping for complete convergence that breaks down in
times of stress. Ironically, in the event of a fiscal union materializing,
Germany will face a daunting challenge of supporting a large part of the
transfers. Germany has been through a similar, (if not the same)
experience, the most recent being the experience of German unification
where the country had to set up the Treuhandanstalt†, step up fiscal
transfers and absorb a large and a substantially poorer labor force. It was
successful. The process culminated in the adoption of the 2010 plan and
Germany bouncing back as the economic power house of Europe. But as
of now, this option is hardly finding favor in the big two (Germany and
France) due to the fiscal burden that may befall them. Notwithstanding
the political challenges en route, a creditable road map towards fiscal
union will undoubtedly be a challenge and require considerable
groundwork.
The third option is the radical one, of peripheral economies leaving the
euro zone. A breakdown of the currency may be a very expensive
proposition. But if that were to happen, it could lead to insolvency of
several Euro zone countries, a breakdown in intra zone payments. Given
that public debt in these countries is present in the balance sheets of
banks and insurance companies across the world, contagion effects and
instability could spread through the financial system. In comparison, the
sub-prime crisis may almost pale into insignificance (Pagano, 2010,
Eichengreen 2007). This outcome also means an end of the European
dream.
28
†
An agency set up to privatize East German enterprises
Concluding observations: The outcome of the current crisis may be a
matter of conjecture. As we have argued, the options, if at all, before the
Euro zone and indeed the EU are very stark. None of the three choices
are simple. Status quo is also not an option. The choices will have to be
political, but the consequences will undoubtedly be economic. The issue
is not any more on how to deal with the current crisis. Rather, to make
the choice on ‘The Euro’ – as Eichengreen put it, to ‘love it or to leave
it’ and depending on that, to do what needs to done. In the end, we
conclude by observing that neither of these two roads would be easy, the
one that carries with it the vision of unification still holds a dream but the
other route may only take the euro economies further apart.
29
Selected References:
a) EU (2011) European Union Statement by the heads of State or Government
of the Euro Area and EU Institutions, Brussels, 21 July.
b) Eichengreen Barry (2010) Euro, Love it or leave it, VOX, May 2010,
accessed on9 August, 2011, http://www.voxeu.org
c) Eichengreen Barry (2008) The Breakup of the Euro Area, NBER Working
Paper No. 13393, University of California, Berkeley
d) IMF (2011) Euro Area Policies: Spillover Report 2011, Washington DC,
Acessed on 12 August, 2011.
http://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/scr/2011/cr11185.pdf
e) Lorenzo Bini Smaghi (2011): Eurozone, European crisis and policy
responses, Speech by Member of the Executive Board of the European
Central Bank, at the Goldman Sachs Global Macro Conference – Asia 2011,
Hong Kong, 22 February 2011. http://www.bis.org/review/
f) Mundell (1961) "A Theory of Optimum Currency Areas". American
Economic Review 51 (4): 657–665.
g) Sirkka Hämäläinen (1999) The euro: the birth of a new currency,
Presentation by, Member, Executive Board of the European Central Bank, at
the meeting of the Institute International d' Etudes Bancaires on 21 May
1999,Helsinki,http://www.ecb.int/press/key/date/1999/html/sp990521.en.htm
l
h) OECD, Education at a Glance 2009: OECD indicators
i) Pagano Marco (2010) Fiscal crisis, contagion, and the future of euro, VOX,
15 May, http://www.voxeu.org/index.php?q=node/5041
30
j) Pavoncello Franco (2011) One for all, All for one, The Euro crisis, World
Affairs, May-June.
Annex tables
Growth in GDP – Selected euro zone economies
2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010
Euro area 1.9 0.9 0.8 2.2 1.7 3.1 2.8 0.4 -4.2 1.8
Germany 1.2 0.0 -0.2 1.2 0.8 3.4 2.7 1.0 -4.7 3.6
France 1.8 0.9 0.9 2.5 1.8 2.5 2.3 -0.1 -2.7 1.5
Ireland 5.7 6.5 4.4 4.6 6.0 5.3 5.6 -3.5 -7.6 -1.0
Greece 4.2 3.4 5.9 4.4 2.3 5.2 4.3 1.0 -2.0 -4.5
Spain 3.6 2.7 3.1 3.3 3.6 4.0 3.6 0.9 -3.7 -0.1
Italy 1.8 0.5 0.0 1.5 0.7 2.0 1.5 -1.3 -5.2 1.3
Portugal 2.0 0.7 -0.9 1.6 0.8 1.4 2.4 0.0 -2.5 1.3
Source: Eurostat
Fiscal Deficit and public debt to GDP ratio (%)
2001 2002 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010
Fiscal Deficit / GDP (%)
Euro area -17 -1.9 -2.6 -2.5 -1.4 -0.7 -2.0 -6.3 -6.0
Germany -2.8 -3.7 -3.3 -1.6 0.3 0.1 -3.0 -3.3
France -1.5 -3.1 -2.9 -2.3 -2.7 -3.3 -7.5 -7.0
Ireland 0.9 -0.4 1.6 2.9 0.1 -7.3 -14.3 -32.4
Greece -4.5 -4.8 -5.2 -5.7 -6.4 -9.8 -15.4 -10.5
Spain -0.6 -0.5 1.0 2.0 1.9 -4.2 -11.1 -9.2
Italy -3.1 -2.9 -4.3 -3.4 -1.5 -2.7 -5.4 -4.6
Portugal -4.3 -2.9 -5.9 -4.1 -3.1 -3.5 -10.1 -9.1
Public debt / GDP (%)
Euro area- 17 68.1 67.9 70 68.4 66.2 69.9 79.3 85.1
Germany 58.8 60.4 68 67.6 64.9 66.3 73.5 83.2
France 56.9 58.8 66.4 63.7 63.9 67.7 78.3 81.7
Ireland 35.5 32.1 27.4 24.8 25.0 44.4 65.6 96.2
Greece 103.7 101.7 100 106.1 105.4 110.7 127.1 142.8
Spain 55.5 52.5 43 39.6 36.1 39.8 53.3 60.1
Italy 108.8 105.7 105.9 106.6 103.6 106.3 116.1 119
Portugal 51.2 53.8 62.8 63.9 68.3 71.6 83.0 93.0
Source: Eurostat
Annex tables
External debt as ratio of GDP
Greece Ireland Spain Portugal Italy
2007 97 535 110 118 92
Growth in GDP – Selected euro zone economies
2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010
Euro area 1.9 0.9 0.8 2.2 1.7 3.1 2.8 0.4 -4.2 1.8
Germany 1.2 0.0 -0.2 1.2 0.8 3.4 2.7 1.0 -4.7 3.6
France 1.8 0.9 0.9 2.5 1.8 2.5 2.3 -0.1 -2.7 1.5
Ireland 5.7 6.5 4.4 4.6 6.0 5.3 5.6 -3.5 -7.6 -1.0
Greece 4.2 3.4 5.9 4.4 2.3 5.2 4.3 1.0 -2.0 -4.5
Spain 3.6 2.7 3.1 3.3 3.6 4.0 3.6 0.9 -3.7 -0.1
Italy 1.8 0.5 0.0 1.5 0.7 2.0 1.5 -1.3 -5.2 1.3
Portugal 2.0 0.7 -0.9 1.6 0.8 1.4 2.4 0.0 -2.5 1.3
Source: Eurostat
Fiscal Deficit and public debt to GDP ratio (%)
2001 2002 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010
Fiscal Deficit / GDP (%)
Euro area -17 -1.9 -2.6 -2.5 -1.4 -0.7 -2.0 -6.3 -6.0
Germany -2.8 -3.7 -3.3 -1.6 0.3 0.1 -3.0 -3.3
France -1.5 -3.1 -2.9 -2.3 -2.7 -3.3 -7.5 -7.0
Ireland 0.9 -0.4 1.6 2.9 0.1 -7.3 -14.3 -32.4
Greece -4.5 -4.8 -5.2 -5.7 -6.4 -9.8 -15.4 -10.5
Spain -0.6 -0.5 1.0 2.0 1.9 -4.2 -11.1 -9.2
Italy -3.1 -2.9 -4.3 -3.4 -1.5 -2.7 -5.4 -4.6
Portugal -4.3 -2.9 -5.9 -4.1 -3.1 -3.5 -10.1 -9.1
Public debt / GDP (%)
Euro area- 17 68.1 67.9 70 68.4 66.2 69.9 79.3 85.1
Germany 58.8 60.4 68 67.6 64.9 66.3 73.5 83.2
France 56.9 58.8 66.4 63.7 63.9 67.7 78.3 81.7
Ireland 35.5 32.1 27.4 24.8 25.0 44.4 65.6 96.2
Greece 103.7 101.7 100 106.1 105.4 110.7 127.1 142.8
Spain 55.5 52.5 43 39.6 36.1 39.8 53.3 60.1
Italy 108.8 105.7 105.9 106.6 103.6 106.3 116.1 119
Portugal 51.2 53.8 62.8 63.9 68.3 71.6 83.0 93.0
Source: Eurostat
31
20
External debt as ratio of GDP
Greece Ireland Spain Portugal Italy
2007 97 535 110 118 92
2008 139 697 68 182 43
Italy 108.8 105.7 105.9 106.6 103.6 106.3 116.1 119
Portugal 51.2 53.8 62.8 63.9 68.3 71.6 83.0 93.0
Source: Eurostat
2009 154 1041 158 207 110
2010 181 1121 171 221 108
Unemployment rate, annual average (%)
Euro area 16 8.1 8.5 8.9 9.0 9.2 8.5 7.6 7.6 9.6 10
Germany 7.6 8.4 9.3 9.8 11.2 10.3 8.7 7.5 7.8 7
Ireland 3.9 4.5 4.6 4.5 4.4 4.5 4.6 6.3 11.9 13
Greece 10.7 10.3 9.7 10.5 9.9 8.9 8.3 7.7 9.5 12
Spain 10.3 11.1 11.1 10.6 9.2 8.5 8.3 11.3 18.0 20
Italy 9.1 8.6 8.4 8.0 7.7 6.8 6.1 6.7 7.8 8
Portugal 4.6 5.7 7.1 7.5 8.6 8.6 8.9 8.5 10.6 12
Source: Eurostat
Ranking of Euro Area in the Global Competitiveness Index 2010–2011
Sub Indexes
Country/
Economy
OVERALL
INDEX
Basic
requirements
Efficiency
enhancers
Innovation and
sophistication
factors
Rank Score Rank Score Rank Score Rank Score
many 5 5.39 6 5.89 13 5.11 5 5.51
and 7 5.37 5 5.97 14 5.09 6 5.43
herlands 8 5.33 9 5.82 8 5.24 8 5.16
nce 15 5.13 16 5.67 15 5.09 16 4.83
tria 18 5.09 15 5.67 19 4.83 13 4.97
ium 19 5.07 22 5.45 17 5.01 15 4.91
embourg 20 5.05 10 5.81 20 4.92 19 4.76
and 29 4.74 35 5.18 25 4.68 21 4.55
nia 33 4.61 25 5.38 34 4.52 45 3.90
rus 40 4.50 29 5.28 36 4.46 36 4.07
n 42 4.49 38 5.13 32 4.56 41 3.96
enia 45 4.42 34 5.18 46 4.33 35 4.08
ugal 46 4.38 42 5.01 43 4.36 39 3.98
y 48 4.37 46 4.84 45 4.33 32 4.11
ta 50 4.34 40 5.08 47 4.31 46 3.88
ak Republic 60 4.25 53 4.77 37 4.43 63 3.54
ece 83 3.99 67 4.49 59 4.12 73 3.41
rce: Global Competitiveness Report 2010–2011, World Economic forum
2009 154 1041 158 207 110
2010 181 1121 171 221 108
Unemployment rate, annual average (%)
Euro area 16 8.1 8.5 8.9 9.0 9.2 8.5 7.6 7.6 9.6 10.1
Germany 7.6 8.4 9.3 9.8 11.2 10.3 8.7 7.5 7.8 7.1
Ireland 3.9 4.5 4.6 4.5 4.4 4.5 4.6 6.3 11.9 13.7
Greece 10.7 10.3 9.7 10.5 9.9 8.9 8.3 7.7 9.5 12.6
Spain 10.3 11.1 11.1 10.6 9.2 8.5 8.3 11.3 18.0 20.1
Italy 9.1 8.6 8.4 8.0 7.7 6.8 6.1 6.7 7.8 8.4
Portugal 4.6 5.7 7.1 7.5 8.6 8.6 8.9 8.5 10.6 12.0
Source: Eurostat
Ranking of Euro Area in the Global Competitiveness Index 2010–2011
Sub Indexes
Country/
Economy
OVERALL
INDEX
Basic
requirements
Efficiency
enhancers
Innovation and
sophistication
factors
Rank Score Rank Score Rank Score Rank Score
Germany 5 5.39 6 5.89 13 5.11 5 5.51
Finland 7 5.37 5 5.97 14 5.09 6 5.43
Netherlands 8 5.33 9 5.82 8 5.24 8 5.16
France 15 5.13 16 5.67 15 5.09 16 4.83
Austria 18 5.09 15 5.67 19 4.83 13 4.97
Belgium 19 5.07 22 5.45 17 5.01 15 4.91
Luxembourg 20 5.05 10 5.81 20 4.92 19 4.76
Ireland 29 4.74 35 5.18 25 4.68 21 4.55
Estonia 33 4.61 25 5.38 34 4.52 45 3.90
Cyprus 40 4.50 29 5.28 36 4.46 36 4.07
Spain 42 4.49 38 5.13 32 4.56 41 3.96
Slovenia 45 4.42 34 5.18 46 4.33 35 4.08
Portugal 46 4.38 42 5.01 43 4.36 39 3.98
Italy 48 4.37 46 4.84 45 4.33 32 4.11
Malta 50 4.34 40 5.08 47 4.31 46 3.88
Slovak Republic 60 4.25 53 4.77 37 4.43 63 3.54
32
21
Ranking of Euro Area in the Global Competitiveness Index 2010–2011
Sub Indexes
Country/
Economy
OVERALL
INDEX
Basic
requirements
Efficiency
enhancers
Innovation and
sophistication
factors
Rank Score Rank Score Rank Score Rank Score
Germany 5 5.39 6 5.89 13 5.11 5 5.51
Finland 7 5.37 5 5.97 14 5.09 6 5.43
Netherlands 8 5.33 9 5.82 8 5.24 8 5.16
France 15 5.13 16 5.67 15 5.09 16 4.83
Austria 18 5.09 15 5.67 19 4.83 13 4.97
Belgium 19 5.07 22 5.45 17 5.01 15 4.91
Luxembourg 20 5.05 10 5.81 20 4.92 19 4.76
Ireland 29 4.74 35 5.18 25 4.68 21 4.55
Estonia 33 4.61 25 5.38 34 4.52 45 3.90
Cyprus 40 4.50 29 5.28 36 4.46 36 4.07
Spain 42 4.49 38 5.13 32 4.56 41 3.96
Slovenia 45 4.42 34 5.18 46 4.33 35 4.08
Portugal 46 4.38 42 5.01 43 4.36 39 3.98
Italy 48 4.37 46 4.84 45 4.33 32 4.11
Malta 50 4.34 40 5.08 47 4.31 46 3.88
Slovak Republic 60 4.25 53 4.77 37 4.43 63 3.54
Greece 83 3.99 67 4.49 59 4.12 73 3.41
Source: Global Competitiveness Report 2010–2011, World Economic forum
33
34
Public Unrest –Greece
35
Endnotes
i
As per the convergence criteria, countries had to keep budget deficit below 3% of GDP, public
debt below 60%, maintain price stability and ensure interest rates remained within limits for at
least 2 yrs to gain admittance to EMU.
ii
The euro zone currently consists of Austria, Belgium, Cyprus, Estonia, Finland, France,
Germany, Greece, Ireland, Italy, Luxembourg, Malta, the Netherlands, Portugal, Slovakia,
Slovenia, and Spain
iii
The success of the Marshall Plan led visionaries like Monnet, Schuman and others to push new
cooperative initiatives like the creation of the European coal and steel community followed by
the Treaty of Rome in 1957 which led to the setting up of the Common Market and spurred
growth in Europe.
iv
Trans-European Automated Real-time Gross Settlement Express Transfer (TARGET) system) is
an interbank and cross-border payment systemin the EU.
v The targeted privatizations include prime tourist real estate, national gambling
monopoly, Post bank, Athens and Thessaloniki ports, Water and Sewer Company and
the telephone company.
vi
Between Jan 2009 to March 2009 the Irish government had to nationalise the Anglo Irish Bank,
the Allied Irish Bank and the Bank of Ireland. These developments were linked to serious lapses
in legal compliance also termed as circular lending (also termed as the Golden circle lending).
vii
In political science, the unparalleled development of the EU as compared to other
international organizations has led to its designation as a sui generis geopolitical entity. The
same could be said about the euro zone.

viii
Other factors not under control include the
expansion of social benefits and the level of productivity.
ix There has already been political fallout of the current crisis in the peripheral euro zone
economies in terms of public unrest in Greece, Italy and to some extent in Spain. At least
two finance ministers have been sacked one in Greece and the other in Italy with the
latest fall out being the resignation of the board member of the ECB.
36
FREQUENTLY ASKED QUESTIONS:
1. What is Euro Debt Crisis ?
2. Can a country leave the euro?
3. What would be the likely trigger for a country leaving the euro?
4. Could a country default and stay within the euro?
5. Would an exit by one country (such as Greece) cause others to leave the
euro?
6. Which countries would be most likely to stay in the euro, and which would
be most likely to leave?
7. What would be the immediate economic and financial consequences for
countries leaving the euro?
8. And for the countries that stayed?

 9. What would be the impact on global financial markets?

10. What would be the impact on the euro in relation to global currencies?
11. Would a global recession be inevitable if the euro collapsed?

12. What would happen to banks in countries that left the euro?

13. Could private debt in euros be enforced?

14. What would happen to sovereign debt?

15. Could EU internal market rules be maintained?

16. Would countries that exited the euro remain in the EU?

17. What levels of social and political upheaval would be expected?

18. What should businesses do now?
37
1. What is Eurozone debt Crisis?
The Eurozone Debt Crisis is an economic crisis due to the collapse of
financial institutions, high government debt, and rapidly rising bond
yield spreads in government securities faced by several European
countries. The European sovereign debt crisis started in 2008, with the
collapse of Iceland's banking system, and spread primarily to Greece,
Ireland and Portugal during 2009. This led to a crisis of confidence for
European businesses and economies.
2. Can a country leave the euro?
Technically, no. However, we assume that under extreme circumstances,
procedural and legal obstacles would not prevent an exit. No formal
mechanism exists for a country to be expelled from the euro area or to leave
of its own volition, and a comprehensively negotiated exit—if even
possible—could take years. Instead, a country might leave unilaterally,
breaching many of its legal obligations to the EU,
its creditors and others. In this messy scenario, uncertainty in the interim over
a country’s formal membership status would quickly become secondary to its
de facto status as a pariah. Alternatively, a stricken country could in effect be
expelled if policy institutions and fellow euro members decided to withhold
financial support, thus pushing the country towards a position in which it felt
unilateral exit was its best choice. The practical challenge of switching
rapidly to a new currency—countries had years to prepare for the introduction
of the euro—would also be formidable.
3. What would be the likely trigger for a country leaving the euro?
It is conceivable but highly unlikely that Germany or another fiscally and
economically strong country might decide to leave the euro. The more likely
eventuality, which we examine here, is that of a
 weak economy such as
Greece leaving. The most likely initial trigger would be a disorderly
sovereign default. This could happen if the country refused to accept harsh
terms for financial support; or if euro institutions, the IMF and other euro
members declined to intervene further on the grounds that the country was
failing to implement effective deficit-cutting measures. The former is most
38
likely. Default would wreak havoc in the domestic banking system because of
banks’ sovereign debt exposure. In fear of bank failures, panic withdrawal of
funds could follow. Unless countered by the provision of sufficient liquidity
from the European Central Bank (ECB), this would in effect lead to the
collapse of the banking system, making normal commercial life impossible.
At this point, the only way to restart commercial activity could be to
introduce a new national currency.
4. Could a country default and stay within the euro?
A default would not automatically imply exit. A country could stay within the
euro if sufficient institutional support and external financing for its banks
were forthcoming. (Fears of systemic contagion, indeed, could make such
support more likely.) The biggest factor would be whether the necessary
political will existed inside the country, among its euro partners and from the
“troika” of the ECB, European Commission and IMF. We believe that the
costs of abandoning the single currency would far outweigh the benefits, such
as currency depreciation that promoted export competitiveness. However,
populist politics and/or opposition from an austerity-fatigued public to further
painful cutbacks could create conditions in which the argument for leaving
the euro appeared persuasive.
5.Would an exit by one country (such as Greece) cause others to
leave the euro?
There is a major risk that it would. For example, if Greece left the euro, the
market pressures on
 the countries perceived as the next most vulnerable
would rapidly become overwhelming. Bond
 yields would skyrocket, making
funding from private markets unaffordable, even on the (generous)
assumption that markets remained willing to lend at exorbitant rates. In one
sense, such sovereign funding issues would not immediately matter for
countries such as Portugal and Ireland, which are supported by a programme
agreement with the European Financial Stability Facility (EFSF) and IMF.
However, it is likely that these countries’ banking sectors would also come
under increasing pressure amid heightened liquidity and solvency fears,
raising immediate funding concerns and possibly triggering runs on deposits.
These pressures could ultimately exceed the willingness of official
institutions to intervene. In the case of countries without fiscal support
programmes, the ECB and EFSF could either choose or feel compelled to
39
intervene, but they might not be able to do so on a sufficient scale to calm the
markets. In both cases, the same process of collapse of the banking system
leading
 to a political decision to exit the euro would then risk being
repeated. The danger is that with each cycle, a bigger and harder-to-save
economy would come under pressure, reducing the chances of policy success.
It is worth noting that the chronology of contagion would be untidy. During
the exit process, severe market pressures would already be present in other
countries as investors priced in the anticipated impact. As the chain reaction
spread across Europe, we think contagion would be rapid, dramatic and
uncontrollable at times, but there might also be periods in which events
moved slowly. For example, in the case of Italy, it would take time for higher
interest costs on newly issued debt to increase the total interest burden to an
unaffordable level. Every escalation of the crisis could also inspire greater
official commitment to saving the euro, which would calm markets
temporarily.
6. Which countries would be most likely to stay in the euro, and
which would be most likely to leave?
Firm predictions are tricky, but broadly a fracture between a strong northern
“core” and the weaker “periphery” looks most likely. The process would, in
our view, probably entail periphery countries breaking off individually to
leave a “rump” of northern countries still within a currency union. Once one
peripheral country (say, Greece) left, all the other vulnerable countries would
probably follow. This means that Portugal, Ireland, Italy and Spain would
leave the euro, although not necessarily immediately. Malta would probably
leave, and Cyprus would have little choice but to exit as its banking system
would be nearly wiped out by a Greek collapse. Up to ten countries could
remain members of the euro: Germany, France, Austria, Belgium, Finland,
Luxembourg, the Netherlands, Slovakia, Slovenia and Estonia (the last three
all being small, open economies like Malta and Cyprus, but with healthier
fundamentals).
France’s status would be key. With memories of the speculative attacks and
devaluations of the 1970s and 1980s still fresh in policymakers’ minds, no
appetite whatsoever exists in the political mainstream for a return to a
national currency. France would therefore make every effort to stay in the
euro. However, a slimmed-down northern core would cause dramatic
40
currency appreciation that would make it difficult for France, with its external
deficit rising as a result, to remain viable in the euro. Nevertheless, we think
that monetary union with Germany is so fundamental to France’s view of its
political and economic interests that it would be determined to stay, and that
Germany would be willing to provide extensive financial support to enable
France to do so. For Germany, close co- operation with France is a more
fundamental part of its political culture than that with the peripheral countries.
If France stayed, the new bloc could still be considered a smaller euro zone; if
it left, the result would in effect be an enlarged D-mark zone.
7. What would be the immediate economic and financial
consequences for countries leaving the euro?
The consequences would be numerous and unpleasant. In anticipation of the
euro exit, an accelerating bank run would be likely, as institutions and
individuals rushed to move their deposits out of the country. This would
severely threaten the banking system and would have to be halted by a
prolonged bank holiday and/or capital controls. While bank withdrawals were
frozen, the government would legislate to create a new currency. It would
redenominate existing bank assets and liabilities into the new currency, and
new banknotes and coins would be created. The new currency would
depreciate dramatically against existing global currencies.
Any debt that remained in euros would be much higher in local-currency
terms. So too would debt in other currencies such as US dollars. The result
would be massive balance-sheet problems, and many companies would
become insolvent. External funding would also be cut off. Public-sector
salaries and most private-sector salaries would have to be paid in the new
currency. The country would suffer a sharp compression of imports, to the
point where it could only import goods and services up to the value of hard
currency it earned through exports. New trade contracts would have to be
denominated in external currencies, as suppliers would want payments in
strong currencies.
If the introduction of a new currency had been preceded by sovereign default,
this would mitigate
 the debt-servicing burden. However, any government
that had not previously achieved a primary fiscal surplus would either have to
implement further austerity (which would be deeply unpopular)
 or monetise
the deficit, which, added to massive currency depreciation, would be highly
41
inflationary. Exiting from the euro would not in the short term prevent savage
recession. At some point in the future, the country might be able to begin to
return to sustainable growth on the basis of regained competitive advantage,
although the difficulty of achieving the necessary internal adjustment could
be formidable. In any event, successful economic reconstruction would only
occur if wages could be reduced in real terms and efforts to compensate for
inflation resisted. Recession in the rest of the euro zone would deplete
demand for the departed country’s exports even after currency depreciation.
Even under this grim general scenario, some economies would fare better
than others. For example, Italy’s well-established export-manufacturing base
and reasonably sound economic fundamentals (domestic debt aside) would
mitigate the damage. Greece, in contrast, lacks a strong industrial base and
would have little in the way of a functioning economy to fall back on.
8. And for the countries that stayed?
The stronger northern core would suffer in three main ways. The most
immediate and dramatic impact of a fracturing of the euro zone would be
massive losses on domestic bank lending to governments and companies in
the countries that had left. This would require major public intervention,
possibly on an even larger scale than in 2008. In turn, this would add
considerably to sovereign debt levels in Germany, France and elsewhere.
Second, sharp currency appreciation would erode export competitiveness.
Third, export demand in neighboring countries, particularly those whose
currencies had depreciated, would collapse. This would have a serious
impact, given the importance of trade between euro members. For example,
Germany sent 41% of its exports to other euro area countries in 2010. For
Austria, the corresponding figure was 54%. In both cases, the “weak”
countries accounted for much lower shares of exports. However, a break-up
of the euro would also cause recession in the stronger core and undermine
global demand, so the overall downturn in exports would be substantial.
9. What would be the impact on global financial markets?
Again, this would depend on the nature and scale of the break-up, but it
would certainly be negative for equities and other risk assets, resulting in
flight to safety on a potentially epic scale. Stock markets would fall
dramatically in most countries. Although investors have already priced in
42
substantial negative expectations, a euro break-up would have a much more
dramatic impact on confidence.
Government bond markets would probably be split between those seen as
relative safe havens and the rest. US bond yields could fall even further as
investors piled into the “risk off” trade. German bunds could also benefit
similarly, although this would depend on market perceptions of Germany’s
success in isolating itself from weaker euro members. As in the aftermath of
the collapse of Lehman Brothers in 2008, dislocations in the short-term
markets that lubricate the global financial system would emerge. In Europe,
the impact of break-up would probably surpass the turmoil seen in the wake
of Lehman’s collapse.
The potential fallout elsewhere in the world is difficult to judge, but with each
new country that left the monetary union, the impact would become more
severe. For example, departure and default
 by Italy—the world’s third-
largest government bond issuer, with bonds worth about US$2.1trn in
circulation—would immediately imperil the solvency of financial services
companies across the world. Those that could not raise sufficient funds to
compensate—a foreseeable problem given that liquidity would be tight—
would have to turn to governments for support. The resultant market turmoil
could be exacerbated by limited capacity for states to support the financial
sector on a similar scale to that in 2008-09.
10. What would be the impact on the euro in relation to global
currencies?
Throughout the initial stages of break-up, the downward forces on the euro
would be severe. If the ECB, for example, vastly expanded its bond-buying
programme—in effect mimicking the US Federal Reserve’s quantitative
easing—in an attempt to contain the crisis, the euro could drop sharply. The
potentially lengthy limbo period during the break-up would also be highly
negative for the single currency, owing to safe-haven factors. Money would
flood into the dollar and potentially into other currencies such as the Swiss
franc. However, if the situation stabilised, the rump euro would be a strong
currency since it would contain only healthier northern economies. The euro
would also benefit from the poor fundamentals of the US dollar, which have
been masked by other factors until now.
43
11. Would a global recession be inevitable if the euro collapsed?
A break-up would cause a deep recession throughout what is now the euro
zone. Demand would weaken because of a combination of consumer
retrenchment, higher unemployment, reduced spending power in countries
that suffered sharp currency depreciation, and weaker exports. At the same
time, the need for austerity would make substantial fiscal stimulus
unaffordable in most west European countries.
We also think serious disruption in the euro area would tip the US into
recession. Moreover, even if the euro area avoids outright break-up, the
uncertainty over the future of the single currency and associated economic
weakness could still have a significant impact on US and global growth. US
exports to the current euro area, which account for about 14% of the total,
would suffer badly. There would also be a negative wealth effect as a result of
sharp falls in US equity prices, which would hit US consumer spending. A
renewed credit crunch driven by severe strains on the financial system would
further limit the economy’s ability to expand.
Other economies, including fast-growing emerging markets like China, would
also be seriously affected. The EU is a major market for many export-oriented
developing countries. Moreover, China is not in a position to match the scale
of the stimulus package that it deployed in response to the global crisis of
2008-09—although the government would still be able to launch a substantial
stimulus, and the approach of a major leadership transition in 2012-13 would
make the Chinese Communist Party
particularly keen to ensure that the economy continues to grow rapidly. It is
also worth stressing that China is not as reliant on exports to drive economic
growth as it was in 2008-09. Nevertheless, Chinese growth would clearly be
hit if the euro zone broke up or went into depression.
12. What would happen to banks in countries that left the euro?
There would be widespread insolvencies. A run on banks in the countries
considered close to leaving the euro would be one of the likeliest triggers to
make an exit reality. As the possibility of a euro exit—and inevitable
devaluation of a new national currency—became more credible, depositors
would rightly transfer their euros to banks in other countries. To a certain
44
extent, this is already happening across the euro area’s periphery. An
acceleration of this trend in Greece, Portugal or any other country believed to
be on its way out of monetary union would devastate domestic banks,
saddling sovereigns with the cost of recapitalisation, which would, in turn,
hasten defaults on government debt. Given that banks hold large amounts of
sovereign debt, this would further weaken lenders’ balance sheets and,
ultimately, lead to the effective bankruptcy of a country’s financial system.
Once a country was outside of the euro zone, domestic loans and deposits
would be redenominated in a new, weaker currency. Restrictions on
withdrawals would be likely. Banks would probably default on most, if not
all, external debt that remained denominated in euros, dollars or other hard
currencies. They would be shunned by international capital markets, and
reliant on funding from official sources. Larger banks might be able to find
some support from income generated at subsidiaries abroad, although
overseas revenue could also suffer indirectly as customers abroad shunned the
beleaguered institutions. (Foreign units could also be sold to raise funds to
cover losses at home.) A country’s pariah status in global markets, and the
likely imposition of capital controls, would mean that banks’ fortunes would
be tied almost entirely to activity in the domestic economy, which would take
years to recover.
13. Could private debt in euros be enforced?
This would depend on whether contracts were under the law of the countries
leaving the euro zone, countries remaining in the euro zone or third countries.
In the first case, the countries concerned would be likely to legislate to
convert all euro contracts into national-currency contracts at the rate at which
the new currency was introduced (despite likely subsequent depreciation).
Contracts in other countries would legally be valid in those countries, but
attempts to enforce such contracts could in many cases lead to companies
declaring bankruptcy, although some multinational companies could probably
survive.
14. What would happen to sovereign debt?
It is likely that foreign sovereign debt would be renounced, or renegotiated
under threat of being renounced. Domestic sovereign debt would be
honoured, but only at the official exchange rate with the new currency.
45
15. Could EU internal market rules be maintained?
Only partly. A key element of the EU internal market is free movement of
capital, and this would almost certainly be abandoned for some years owing
to the introduction of capital controls to prevent all the new money being
exchanged for foreign currency. It is also quite possible that other member
states would restrict free movement of labour, to avoid a huge exodus of
workers to other countries in the EU. The abrogation of these rules would
provide a dangerous precedent. However, the interests both of countries that
had left the euro zone and of the rest would be served by maintaining rules to
enable a reduced level of trade in goods and services to continue.
16. Would countries that exited the euro remain in the EU?
We think so. If the assumption is that efforts would be made to maintain an
internal market for the movement of goods and services, remaining in the EU
would be the best way of enabling this to happen. Although it is possible to
exist outside the EU and enjoy some of the benefits of membership— as in
the non-EU states of Norway, Iceland and Switzerland, which are effectively
integrated into most aspects of the EU internal market—it is still difficult to
see why countries leaving the euro zone would leave the EU. Remaining in
the EU would make it easier for internal market rules other than those on free
movement of capital and labour to be observed.
17. What levels of social and political upheaval would be expected?
Violent protests took place when deposits were frozen during the Argentinian
crisis of 2001, and similar turbulence could occur in countries leaving the
euro. Depositors would only be able to withdraw money eventually and in a
new, depreciated currency. Falls in real incomes and possible shortages of
imported goods would cause huge stresses. These could worsen, leading to
further social and economic breakdown in subsequent years. However, it
might also be possible to rebuild trust gradually as people worked together to
overcome problems and the new currency stabilised.
Considerable social tensions could also be seen in countries that remained in
the euro. In France, for example, further severe austerity would be needed to
match German demands and reassure markets.
18. What should businesses do now?
46
Businesses need to make contingency plans and review risk-management
processes in much the same way that they would consider the impact of other
major events, whether it be a natural disaster, political upheaval or the loss of
a major customer. Contingency plans would depend on the nature of the
company’s business and its direct exposure to the euro zone, but in general
terms the main issues to consider could include finance and cash
management, business continuity, revenue assumptions and targets, and client
and supply chains. Below is a list of more specific actions that might be
necessary:
 Adjust Internal budget assumptions and targets to take account of much
weaker economic conditions both in the euro zone and globally.
 Examine Supply chains (going back several levels, to suppliers’
suppliers) and identify weak links. Which suppliers might go out of
business?
 Prepare for supply-chain disruptions, for example by increasing
precautionary inventories of business-critical components sourced from
euro zone countries, in case supply is interrupted.
 Establish or expand alternative supplier arrangements in non-euro
countries.
 
 Examine client relationships to determine which clients might
experience financial difficulties that would prevent them from making
payments or renewing contracts.
 As with supply chains, consider diversifying revenue risk by expanding
client bases in non-euro countries.
 Limit the time cash balances are held in banks in at-risk
countries.
 invoicing and billing systems, in case these need to be
reconfigured to reflect changes incurrency regimes. Are internal
systems robust and flexible enough to cope?
 Prepare for potential disruptions to agents conducting business on the
company’s behalf in at-risk countries, and to mission-critical partners
such as payroll services providers. Consider contingencies such as
sourcing alternative agents and partners.
 Evaluate financial-management policy. Consider the impact of (a)
extreme movements in exchange rates, (b) extreme movements in asset
prices or (c) the sudden loss of access to credit. Are counterparties
financially secure?
 Ensure bank relationships are the right ones. If possible, assess whether
47
the banks on which the company relies are healthy enough to withstand
the collapse of the euro.
 Firm up funding arrangements in advance, putting in place guaranteed
lines of credit if possible. Assess internal reserves of cash.
 Re-examine contracts written in euros or with entities exposed to the
euro crisis. Determine the extent of possible losses should contracts not
be honoured, along with threats to the company’s own ability to honour
contracts.
 Look to lower costs and maximise operational efficiencies. Use crisis
preparation to help drive organisational change, replacing obsolete or
underperforming product lines.
 Make contingency plans for the possibility of political or social unrest
in euro countries, and evaluate the security of physical assets and staff.
Thank You

More Related Content

What's hot

Euro Birth and Impact on International Trade
Euro Birth and Impact on International TradeEuro Birth and Impact on International Trade
Euro Birth and Impact on International TradeMadhusudan Partani
 
EC4024_Data_Project-Greece
EC4024_Data_Project-GreeceEC4024_Data_Project-Greece
EC4024_Data_Project-GreeceLonan Carroll
 
The history of EU and its current situation.
The history of EU and its current situation.The history of EU and its current situation.
The history of EU and its current situation.Rajashree Swain
 
Eurozone Crisis : A case study on Greece
Eurozone Crisis : A case study on GreeceEurozone Crisis : A case study on Greece
Eurozone Crisis : A case study on GreeceAniket Pant
 
Eurozone debt crisis
Eurozone debt crisisEurozone debt crisis
Eurozone debt crisistomarricha
 
European Debt Crisis
European Debt CrisisEuropean Debt Crisis
European Debt CrisisCharu Rastogi
 
Understanding the european debt crisis
Understanding the european debt crisisUnderstanding the european debt crisis
Understanding the european debt crisisAmens Corner Capital
 
Euro debt crisis
Euro debt crisisEuro debt crisis
Euro debt crisisPVAbhi
 
POSITION PAPER: Euro Zone Crisis. Diagnosis and Likely Solutions (ESADEgeo)
POSITION PAPER: Euro Zone Crisis. Diagnosis and Likely Solutions (ESADEgeo)POSITION PAPER: Euro Zone Crisis. Diagnosis and Likely Solutions (ESADEgeo)
POSITION PAPER: Euro Zone Crisis. Diagnosis and Likely Solutions (ESADEgeo)ESADE
 
Euro Sovereign Debt Crisis
Euro Sovereign Debt CrisisEuro Sovereign Debt Crisis
Euro Sovereign Debt CrisisShikher Kaushik
 
Assignment on Greek economics Crisis
Assignment on Greek economics Crisis Assignment on Greek economics Crisis
Assignment on Greek economics Crisis Nirin Parikh
 
European sovereign debt crisis
European sovereign debt crisisEuropean sovereign debt crisis
European sovereign debt crisisPinkesh Jain
 
Lazard Investment Research: Sunset Boulevard, An Interim Report on the Develo...
Lazard Investment Research: Sunset Boulevard, An Interim Report on the Develo...Lazard Investment Research: Sunset Boulevard, An Interim Report on the Develo...
Lazard Investment Research: Sunset Boulevard, An Interim Report on the Develo...LazardLazard
 
Understanding The European Debt Crisis
Understanding The European Debt CrisisUnderstanding The European Debt Crisis
Understanding The European Debt CrisisJGreene Financial
 
Ivo Pezzuto - "GREXIT": AVOIDED FOR NOW! (The Global Analyst Magazine August...
Ivo Pezzuto - "GREXIT": AVOIDED FOR NOW!  (The Global Analyst Magazine August...Ivo Pezzuto - "GREXIT": AVOIDED FOR NOW!  (The Global Analyst Magazine August...
Ivo Pezzuto - "GREXIT": AVOIDED FOR NOW! (The Global Analyst Magazine August...Dr. Ivo Pezzuto
 

What's hot (20)

Euro Birth and Impact on International Trade
Euro Birth and Impact on International TradeEuro Birth and Impact on International Trade
Euro Birth and Impact on International Trade
 
Eurozone crisis
Eurozone crisisEurozone crisis
Eurozone crisis
 
EC4024_Data_Project-Greece
EC4024_Data_Project-GreeceEC4024_Data_Project-Greece
EC4024_Data_Project-Greece
 
The history of EU and its current situation.
The history of EU and its current situation.The history of EU and its current situation.
The history of EU and its current situation.
 
Eurozone Crisis : A case study on Greece
Eurozone Crisis : A case study on GreeceEurozone Crisis : A case study on Greece
Eurozone Crisis : A case study on Greece
 
Eurozone debt crisis
Eurozone debt crisisEurozone debt crisis
Eurozone debt crisis
 
European Debt Crisis
European Debt CrisisEuropean Debt Crisis
European Debt Crisis
 
Understanding the european debt crisis
Understanding the european debt crisisUnderstanding the european debt crisis
Understanding the european debt crisis
 
Euro debt crisis
Euro debt crisisEuro debt crisis
Euro debt crisis
 
POSITION PAPER: Euro Zone Crisis. Diagnosis and Likely Solutions (ESADEgeo)
POSITION PAPER: Euro Zone Crisis. Diagnosis and Likely Solutions (ESADEgeo)POSITION PAPER: Euro Zone Crisis. Diagnosis and Likely Solutions (ESADEgeo)
POSITION PAPER: Euro Zone Crisis. Diagnosis and Likely Solutions (ESADEgeo)
 
Euro Sovereign Debt Crisis
Euro Sovereign Debt CrisisEuro Sovereign Debt Crisis
Euro Sovereign Debt Crisis
 
Euro crisis
Euro crisis Euro crisis
Euro crisis
 
Eurozone Crisis
Eurozone Crisis Eurozone Crisis
Eurozone Crisis
 
The Economic and Monetary Union: Past, Present and Future
The Economic and Monetary Union: Past, Present and FutureThe Economic and Monetary Union: Past, Present and Future
The Economic and Monetary Union: Past, Present and Future
 
Assignment on Greek economics Crisis
Assignment on Greek economics Crisis Assignment on Greek economics Crisis
Assignment on Greek economics Crisis
 
European sovereign debt crisis
European sovereign debt crisisEuropean sovereign debt crisis
European sovereign debt crisis
 
Lazard Investment Research: Sunset Boulevard, An Interim Report on the Develo...
Lazard Investment Research: Sunset Boulevard, An Interim Report on the Develo...Lazard Investment Research: Sunset Boulevard, An Interim Report on the Develo...
Lazard Investment Research: Sunset Boulevard, An Interim Report on the Develo...
 
EMUDebtCrisis
EMUDebtCrisisEMUDebtCrisis
EMUDebtCrisis
 
Understanding The European Debt Crisis
Understanding The European Debt CrisisUnderstanding The European Debt Crisis
Understanding The European Debt Crisis
 
Ivo Pezzuto - "GREXIT": AVOIDED FOR NOW! (The Global Analyst Magazine August...
Ivo Pezzuto - "GREXIT": AVOIDED FOR NOW!  (The Global Analyst Magazine August...Ivo Pezzuto - "GREXIT": AVOIDED FOR NOW!  (The Global Analyst Magazine August...
Ivo Pezzuto - "GREXIT": AVOIDED FOR NOW! (The Global Analyst Magazine August...
 

Viewers also liked

CV Lewandowski Mark 14Mar14
CV Lewandowski Mark 14Mar14CV Lewandowski Mark 14Mar14
CV Lewandowski Mark 14Mar14Mark Lewandowski
 
Koh Tze Loong CV for pharma Nov 2015
Koh Tze Loong CV for pharma Nov 2015Koh Tze Loong CV for pharma Nov 2015
Koh Tze Loong CV for pharma Nov 2015koh tze loong
 
MAHCP Employer Conference Panel Presentation
MAHCP Employer Conference Panel PresentationMAHCP Employer Conference Panel Presentation
MAHCP Employer Conference Panel PresentationEmily Tosoni (Epperson)
 
Business plan Watsdown App
Business plan Watsdown AppBusiness plan Watsdown App
Business plan Watsdown AppBernard Mugume
 
10 fisa functii recursive 1 23feb2012
10 fisa functii recursive 1   23feb201210 fisa functii recursive 1   23feb2012
10 fisa functii recursive 1 23feb2012Radu Danni
 
Organos de la Jurisdiccion Inmobiliaria
Organos de la Jurisdiccion InmobiliariaOrganos de la Jurisdiccion Inmobiliaria
Organos de la Jurisdiccion InmobiliariaBladimir Peña
 
Wealthsimple Lunch & Learn @ OneEleven - 20141104
Wealthsimple Lunch & Learn @ OneEleven - 20141104Wealthsimple Lunch & Learn @ OneEleven - 20141104
Wealthsimple Lunch & Learn @ OneEleven - 20141104Wealthsimple
 
Veloci ti by Qnet عرض منتج شركة كيونت
Veloci ti by Qnet عرض منتج شركة كيونت Veloci ti by Qnet عرض منتج شركة كيونت
Veloci ti by Qnet عرض منتج شركة كيونت QNet Egypt
 
A presentation on the evolution of still camera
A presentation on the evolution of still cameraA presentation on the evolution of still camera
A presentation on the evolution of still cameraPalash Awasthi
 
Suport 01-cls9-tic-cap05-utilizarea internetului
Suport 01-cls9-tic-cap05-utilizarea internetuluiSuport 01-cls9-tic-cap05-utilizarea internetului
Suport 01-cls9-tic-cap05-utilizarea internetuluiGeorge Brebenel
 
Isaf it security_2015
Isaf it security_2015Isaf it security_2015
Isaf it security_2015Mustafa Kuğu
 
20 quick and easy cleaning tips that can really help in commercial cleaning
20 quick and easy cleaning tips that can really help in commercial cleaning20 quick and easy cleaning tips that can really help in commercial cleaning
20 quick and easy cleaning tips that can really help in commercial cleaningPedro Martaan
 

Viewers also liked (15)

CV Lewandowski Mark 14Mar14
CV Lewandowski Mark 14Mar14CV Lewandowski Mark 14Mar14
CV Lewandowski Mark 14Mar14
 
Test i
Test iTest i
Test i
 
Deal Book
Deal BookDeal Book
Deal Book
 
Koh Tze Loong CV for pharma Nov 2015
Koh Tze Loong CV for pharma Nov 2015Koh Tze Loong CV for pharma Nov 2015
Koh Tze Loong CV for pharma Nov 2015
 
MAHCP Employer Conference Panel Presentation
MAHCP Employer Conference Panel PresentationMAHCP Employer Conference Panel Presentation
MAHCP Employer Conference Panel Presentation
 
Business plan Watsdown App
Business plan Watsdown AppBusiness plan Watsdown App
Business plan Watsdown App
 
10 fisa functii recursive 1 23feb2012
10 fisa functii recursive 1   23feb201210 fisa functii recursive 1   23feb2012
10 fisa functii recursive 1 23feb2012
 
Organos de la Jurisdiccion Inmobiliaria
Organos de la Jurisdiccion InmobiliariaOrganos de la Jurisdiccion Inmobiliaria
Organos de la Jurisdiccion Inmobiliaria
 
Wealthsimple Lunch & Learn @ OneEleven - 20141104
Wealthsimple Lunch & Learn @ OneEleven - 20141104Wealthsimple Lunch & Learn @ OneEleven - 20141104
Wealthsimple Lunch & Learn @ OneEleven - 20141104
 
Veloci ti by Qnet عرض منتج شركة كيونت
Veloci ti by Qnet عرض منتج شركة كيونت Veloci ti by Qnet عرض منتج شركة كيونت
Veloci ti by Qnet عرض منتج شركة كيونت
 
A presentation on the evolution of still camera
A presentation on the evolution of still cameraA presentation on the evolution of still camera
A presentation on the evolution of still camera
 
Suport 01-cls9-tic-cap05-utilizarea internetului
Suport 01-cls9-tic-cap05-utilizarea internetuluiSuport 01-cls9-tic-cap05-utilizarea internetului
Suport 01-cls9-tic-cap05-utilizarea internetului
 
441 presentation
441 presentation441 presentation
441 presentation
 
Isaf it security_2015
Isaf it security_2015Isaf it security_2015
Isaf it security_2015
 
20 quick and easy cleaning tips that can really help in commercial cleaning
20 quick and easy cleaning tips that can really help in commercial cleaning20 quick and easy cleaning tips that can really help in commercial cleaning
20 quick and easy cleaning tips that can really help in commercial cleaning
 

Similar to The euro zone crisis jkn-kini

The turbulent adolescence of the euro and its path tomaturity by Gonzalo Garc...
The turbulent adolescence of the euro and its path tomaturity by Gonzalo Garc...The turbulent adolescence of the euro and its path tomaturity by Gonzalo Garc...
The turbulent adolescence of the euro and its path tomaturity by Gonzalo Garc...Círculo de Empresarios
 
The EU at a Crossroads: An Action Plan
The EU at a Crossroads: An Action PlanThe EU at a Crossroads: An Action Plan
The EU at a Crossroads: An Action Planthinkingeurope2011
 
The European Union at a Crossroads: An Action Plan
The European Union at a Crossroads: An Action PlanThe European Union at a Crossroads: An Action Plan
The European Union at a Crossroads: An Action Planthinkingeurope2011
 
Shocking aspectsofmonetaryunion
Shocking aspectsofmonetaryunionShocking aspectsofmonetaryunion
Shocking aspectsofmonetaryunionOldegar Simoes
 
The greek sovereign debt crisis
The greek sovereign debt crisisThe greek sovereign debt crisis
The greek sovereign debt crisisAnkit Kumar
 
Pensions and the European Debt Crisis
Pensions and the European Debt CrisisPensions and the European Debt Crisis
Pensions and the European Debt CrisisAegon
 
Euro Debt Crisis in Greece
Euro Debt Crisis in GreeceEuro Debt Crisis in Greece
Euro Debt Crisis in GreeceNeelum nawab
 
Euro crisis
Euro crisisEuro crisis
Euro crisisRS P
 
Greece And Its Relationship With The Eurozone
Greece And Its Relationship With The EurozoneGreece And Its Relationship With The Eurozone
Greece And Its Relationship With The EurozoneMelissa Williams
 
The causes of the debt crisis in Greece
The causes of the debt crisis in GreeceThe causes of the debt crisis in Greece
The causes of the debt crisis in GreeceAlexanderKorvin
 

Similar to The euro zone crisis jkn-kini (19)

The turbulent adolescence of the euro and its path tomaturity by Gonzalo Garc...
The turbulent adolescence of the euro and its path tomaturity by Gonzalo Garc...The turbulent adolescence of the euro and its path tomaturity by Gonzalo Garc...
The turbulent adolescence of the euro and its path tomaturity by Gonzalo Garc...
 
Impact of Debt Crisis on EMU
Impact of Debt Crisis on EMUImpact of Debt Crisis on EMU
Impact of Debt Crisis on EMU
 
The EU at a Crossroads: An Action Plan
The EU at a Crossroads: An Action PlanThe EU at a Crossroads: An Action Plan
The EU at a Crossroads: An Action Plan
 
The European Union at a Crossroads: An Action Plan
The European Union at a Crossroads: An Action PlanThe European Union at a Crossroads: An Action Plan
The European Union at a Crossroads: An Action Plan
 
Eurozone
EurozoneEurozone
Eurozone
 
Shocking aspectsofmonetaryunion
Shocking aspectsofmonetaryunionShocking aspectsofmonetaryunion
Shocking aspectsofmonetaryunion
 
merged_document
merged_documentmerged_document
merged_document
 
R42377
R42377R42377
R42377
 
LLM University of Reading 2013
LLM University of Reading 2013LLM University of Reading 2013
LLM University of Reading 2013
 
The greek sovereign debt crisis
The greek sovereign debt crisisThe greek sovereign debt crisis
The greek sovereign debt crisis
 
Pensions and the European Debt Crisis
Pensions and the European Debt CrisisPensions and the European Debt Crisis
Pensions and the European Debt Crisis
 
Eurobonds
EurobondsEurobonds
Eurobonds
 
Euro Debt Crisis in Greece
Euro Debt Crisis in GreeceEuro Debt Crisis in Greece
Euro Debt Crisis in Greece
 
Europe without the EU?
Europe without the EU?Europe without the EU?
Europe without the EU?
 
Euro crisis
Euro crisisEuro crisis
Euro crisis
 
Greece And Its Relationship With The Eurozone
Greece And Its Relationship With The EurozoneGreece And Its Relationship With The Eurozone
Greece And Its Relationship With The Eurozone
 
CASE Network Studies and Analyses 256 - Nominal and Real Convergence in Spain...
CASE Network Studies and Analyses 256 - Nominal and Real Convergence in Spain...CASE Network Studies and Analyses 256 - Nominal and Real Convergence in Spain...
CASE Network Studies and Analyses 256 - Nominal and Real Convergence in Spain...
 
Research - debt crisis
Research - debt crisis Research - debt crisis
Research - debt crisis
 
The causes of the debt crisis in Greece
The causes of the debt crisis in GreeceThe causes of the debt crisis in Greece
The causes of the debt crisis in Greece
 

Recently uploaded

Call Girls in DELHI Cantt, ( Call Me )-8377877756-Female Escort- In Delhi / Ncr
Call Girls in DELHI Cantt, ( Call Me )-8377877756-Female Escort- In Delhi / NcrCall Girls in DELHI Cantt, ( Call Me )-8377877756-Female Escort- In Delhi / Ncr
Call Girls in DELHI Cantt, ( Call Me )-8377877756-Female Escort- In Delhi / Ncrdollysharma2066
 
Lowrate Call Girls In Sector 18 Noida ❤️8860477959 Escorts 100% Genuine Servi...
Lowrate Call Girls In Sector 18 Noida ❤️8860477959 Escorts 100% Genuine Servi...Lowrate Call Girls In Sector 18 Noida ❤️8860477959 Escorts 100% Genuine Servi...
Lowrate Call Girls In Sector 18 Noida ❤️8860477959 Escorts 100% Genuine Servi...lizamodels9
 
Call Girls In Connaught Place Delhi ❤️88604**77959_Russian 100% Genuine Escor...
Call Girls In Connaught Place Delhi ❤️88604**77959_Russian 100% Genuine Escor...Call Girls In Connaught Place Delhi ❤️88604**77959_Russian 100% Genuine Escor...
Call Girls In Connaught Place Delhi ❤️88604**77959_Russian 100% Genuine Escor...lizamodels9
 
MAHA Global and IPR: Do Actions Speak Louder Than Words?
MAHA Global and IPR: Do Actions Speak Louder Than Words?MAHA Global and IPR: Do Actions Speak Louder Than Words?
MAHA Global and IPR: Do Actions Speak Louder Than Words?Olivia Kresic
 
8447779800, Low rate Call girls in Saket Delhi NCR
8447779800, Low rate Call girls in Saket Delhi NCR8447779800, Low rate Call girls in Saket Delhi NCR
8447779800, Low rate Call girls in Saket Delhi NCRashishs7044
 
Lean: From Theory to Practice — One City’s (and Library’s) Lean Story… Abridged
Lean: From Theory to Practice — One City’s (and Library’s) Lean Story… AbridgedLean: From Theory to Practice — One City’s (and Library’s) Lean Story… Abridged
Lean: From Theory to Practice — One City’s (and Library’s) Lean Story… AbridgedKaiNexus
 
Call Girls In Sikandarpur Gurgaon ❤️8860477959_Russian 100% Genuine Escorts I...
Call Girls In Sikandarpur Gurgaon ❤️8860477959_Russian 100% Genuine Escorts I...Call Girls In Sikandarpur Gurgaon ❤️8860477959_Russian 100% Genuine Escorts I...
Call Girls In Sikandarpur Gurgaon ❤️8860477959_Russian 100% Genuine Escorts I...lizamodels9
 
Call Girls In Radisson Blu Hotel New Delhi Paschim Vihar ❤️8860477959 Escorts...
Call Girls In Radisson Blu Hotel New Delhi Paschim Vihar ❤️8860477959 Escorts...Call Girls In Radisson Blu Hotel New Delhi Paschim Vihar ❤️8860477959 Escorts...
Call Girls In Radisson Blu Hotel New Delhi Paschim Vihar ❤️8860477959 Escorts...lizamodels9
 
FULL ENJOY Call girls in Paharganj Delhi | 8377087607
FULL ENJOY Call girls in Paharganj Delhi | 8377087607FULL ENJOY Call girls in Paharganj Delhi | 8377087607
FULL ENJOY Call girls in Paharganj Delhi | 8377087607dollysharma2066
 
BEST Call Girls In Old Faridabad ✨ 9773824855 ✨ Escorts Service In Delhi Ncr,
BEST Call Girls In Old Faridabad ✨ 9773824855 ✨ Escorts Service In Delhi Ncr,BEST Call Girls In Old Faridabad ✨ 9773824855 ✨ Escorts Service In Delhi Ncr,
BEST Call Girls In Old Faridabad ✨ 9773824855 ✨ Escorts Service In Delhi Ncr,noida100girls
 
Kenya Coconut Production Presentation by Dr. Lalith Perera
Kenya Coconut Production Presentation by Dr. Lalith PereraKenya Coconut Production Presentation by Dr. Lalith Perera
Kenya Coconut Production Presentation by Dr. Lalith Pereraictsugar
 
Marketplace and Quality Assurance Presentation - Vincent Chirchir
Marketplace and Quality Assurance Presentation - Vincent ChirchirMarketplace and Quality Assurance Presentation - Vincent Chirchir
Marketplace and Quality Assurance Presentation - Vincent Chirchirictsugar
 
NewBase 19 April 2024 Energy News issue - 1717 by Khaled Al Awadi.pdf
NewBase  19 April  2024  Energy News issue - 1717 by Khaled Al Awadi.pdfNewBase  19 April  2024  Energy News issue - 1717 by Khaled Al Awadi.pdf
NewBase 19 April 2024 Energy News issue - 1717 by Khaled Al Awadi.pdfKhaled Al Awadi
 
8447779800, Low rate Call girls in Shivaji Enclave Delhi NCR
8447779800, Low rate Call girls in Shivaji Enclave Delhi NCR8447779800, Low rate Call girls in Shivaji Enclave Delhi NCR
8447779800, Low rate Call girls in Shivaji Enclave Delhi NCRashishs7044
 
(Best) ENJOY Call Girls in Faridabad Ex | 8377087607
(Best) ENJOY Call Girls in Faridabad Ex | 8377087607(Best) ENJOY Call Girls in Faridabad Ex | 8377087607
(Best) ENJOY Call Girls in Faridabad Ex | 8377087607dollysharma2066
 
Flow Your Strategy at Flight Levels Day 2024
Flow Your Strategy at Flight Levels Day 2024Flow Your Strategy at Flight Levels Day 2024
Flow Your Strategy at Flight Levels Day 2024Kirill Klimov
 
Call Girls In Sikandarpur Gurgaon ❤️8860477959_Russian 100% Genuine Escorts I...
Call Girls In Sikandarpur Gurgaon ❤️8860477959_Russian 100% Genuine Escorts I...Call Girls In Sikandarpur Gurgaon ❤️8860477959_Russian 100% Genuine Escorts I...
Call Girls In Sikandarpur Gurgaon ❤️8860477959_Russian 100% Genuine Escorts I...lizamodels9
 
India Consumer 2024 Redacted Sample Report
India Consumer 2024 Redacted Sample ReportIndia Consumer 2024 Redacted Sample Report
India Consumer 2024 Redacted Sample ReportMintel Group
 
Market Sizes Sample Report - 2024 Edition
Market Sizes Sample Report - 2024 EditionMarket Sizes Sample Report - 2024 Edition
Market Sizes Sample Report - 2024 EditionMintel Group
 

Recently uploaded (20)

Call Girls in DELHI Cantt, ( Call Me )-8377877756-Female Escort- In Delhi / Ncr
Call Girls in DELHI Cantt, ( Call Me )-8377877756-Female Escort- In Delhi / NcrCall Girls in DELHI Cantt, ( Call Me )-8377877756-Female Escort- In Delhi / Ncr
Call Girls in DELHI Cantt, ( Call Me )-8377877756-Female Escort- In Delhi / Ncr
 
Lowrate Call Girls In Sector 18 Noida ❤️8860477959 Escorts 100% Genuine Servi...
Lowrate Call Girls In Sector 18 Noida ❤️8860477959 Escorts 100% Genuine Servi...Lowrate Call Girls In Sector 18 Noida ❤️8860477959 Escorts 100% Genuine Servi...
Lowrate Call Girls In Sector 18 Noida ❤️8860477959 Escorts 100% Genuine Servi...
 
Call Girls In Connaught Place Delhi ❤️88604**77959_Russian 100% Genuine Escor...
Call Girls In Connaught Place Delhi ❤️88604**77959_Russian 100% Genuine Escor...Call Girls In Connaught Place Delhi ❤️88604**77959_Russian 100% Genuine Escor...
Call Girls In Connaught Place Delhi ❤️88604**77959_Russian 100% Genuine Escor...
 
MAHA Global and IPR: Do Actions Speak Louder Than Words?
MAHA Global and IPR: Do Actions Speak Louder Than Words?MAHA Global and IPR: Do Actions Speak Louder Than Words?
MAHA Global and IPR: Do Actions Speak Louder Than Words?
 
8447779800, Low rate Call girls in Saket Delhi NCR
8447779800, Low rate Call girls in Saket Delhi NCR8447779800, Low rate Call girls in Saket Delhi NCR
8447779800, Low rate Call girls in Saket Delhi NCR
 
Lean: From Theory to Practice — One City’s (and Library’s) Lean Story… Abridged
Lean: From Theory to Practice — One City’s (and Library’s) Lean Story… AbridgedLean: From Theory to Practice — One City’s (and Library’s) Lean Story… Abridged
Lean: From Theory to Practice — One City’s (and Library’s) Lean Story… Abridged
 
Call Girls In Sikandarpur Gurgaon ❤️8860477959_Russian 100% Genuine Escorts I...
Call Girls In Sikandarpur Gurgaon ❤️8860477959_Russian 100% Genuine Escorts I...Call Girls In Sikandarpur Gurgaon ❤️8860477959_Russian 100% Genuine Escorts I...
Call Girls In Sikandarpur Gurgaon ❤️8860477959_Russian 100% Genuine Escorts I...
 
Call Girls In Radisson Blu Hotel New Delhi Paschim Vihar ❤️8860477959 Escorts...
Call Girls In Radisson Blu Hotel New Delhi Paschim Vihar ❤️8860477959 Escorts...Call Girls In Radisson Blu Hotel New Delhi Paschim Vihar ❤️8860477959 Escorts...
Call Girls In Radisson Blu Hotel New Delhi Paschim Vihar ❤️8860477959 Escorts...
 
FULL ENJOY Call girls in Paharganj Delhi | 8377087607
FULL ENJOY Call girls in Paharganj Delhi | 8377087607FULL ENJOY Call girls in Paharganj Delhi | 8377087607
FULL ENJOY Call girls in Paharganj Delhi | 8377087607
 
Corporate Profile 47Billion Information Technology
Corporate Profile 47Billion Information TechnologyCorporate Profile 47Billion Information Technology
Corporate Profile 47Billion Information Technology
 
BEST Call Girls In Old Faridabad ✨ 9773824855 ✨ Escorts Service In Delhi Ncr,
BEST Call Girls In Old Faridabad ✨ 9773824855 ✨ Escorts Service In Delhi Ncr,BEST Call Girls In Old Faridabad ✨ 9773824855 ✨ Escorts Service In Delhi Ncr,
BEST Call Girls In Old Faridabad ✨ 9773824855 ✨ Escorts Service In Delhi Ncr,
 
Kenya Coconut Production Presentation by Dr. Lalith Perera
Kenya Coconut Production Presentation by Dr. Lalith PereraKenya Coconut Production Presentation by Dr. Lalith Perera
Kenya Coconut Production Presentation by Dr. Lalith Perera
 
Marketplace and Quality Assurance Presentation - Vincent Chirchir
Marketplace and Quality Assurance Presentation - Vincent ChirchirMarketplace and Quality Assurance Presentation - Vincent Chirchir
Marketplace and Quality Assurance Presentation - Vincent Chirchir
 
NewBase 19 April 2024 Energy News issue - 1717 by Khaled Al Awadi.pdf
NewBase  19 April  2024  Energy News issue - 1717 by Khaled Al Awadi.pdfNewBase  19 April  2024  Energy News issue - 1717 by Khaled Al Awadi.pdf
NewBase 19 April 2024 Energy News issue - 1717 by Khaled Al Awadi.pdf
 
8447779800, Low rate Call girls in Shivaji Enclave Delhi NCR
8447779800, Low rate Call girls in Shivaji Enclave Delhi NCR8447779800, Low rate Call girls in Shivaji Enclave Delhi NCR
8447779800, Low rate Call girls in Shivaji Enclave Delhi NCR
 
(Best) ENJOY Call Girls in Faridabad Ex | 8377087607
(Best) ENJOY Call Girls in Faridabad Ex | 8377087607(Best) ENJOY Call Girls in Faridabad Ex | 8377087607
(Best) ENJOY Call Girls in Faridabad Ex | 8377087607
 
Flow Your Strategy at Flight Levels Day 2024
Flow Your Strategy at Flight Levels Day 2024Flow Your Strategy at Flight Levels Day 2024
Flow Your Strategy at Flight Levels Day 2024
 
Call Girls In Sikandarpur Gurgaon ❤️8860477959_Russian 100% Genuine Escorts I...
Call Girls In Sikandarpur Gurgaon ❤️8860477959_Russian 100% Genuine Escorts I...Call Girls In Sikandarpur Gurgaon ❤️8860477959_Russian 100% Genuine Escorts I...
Call Girls In Sikandarpur Gurgaon ❤️8860477959_Russian 100% Genuine Escorts I...
 
India Consumer 2024 Redacted Sample Report
India Consumer 2024 Redacted Sample ReportIndia Consumer 2024 Redacted Sample Report
India Consumer 2024 Redacted Sample Report
 
Market Sizes Sample Report - 2024 Edition
Market Sizes Sample Report - 2024 EditionMarket Sizes Sample Report - 2024 Edition
Market Sizes Sample Report - 2024 Edition
 

The euro zone crisis jkn-kini

  • 1. 1 The Euro Zone Crisis,
 Its dimensions and Implications by J.K.Nanda Kini Nagendra ITM –Vashi XMBA-21
  • 2. 2 Content Page No Abstract 03 Introduction 04 The Euro Zone: A background 05 Creation of the Euro: its Justification 06 Convergence, cohabitation and divergence 06 From the global crisis to the Euro zone crisis 11 The rescue: creation of the EFSF and the ESM 13 Some critical dimensions of the EZC 17 A monetary union without a fiscal union Structural differences 
 Cross border lending 
 Decision making in the Euro zone Implications and Possible directions 22 Implications for the advanced countries: Euro zone crisis and the EMEs
 Possible directions Concluding observations 27 References
 28 Annex tables
 29 Endnotes 33 FAQs 34 Abstract:
  • 3. 3 The sovereign debt problems in the peripheral economies of the euro zone has started to pose a serious threat to the main economies of the Europe and perhaps to the future of the ̳euro‘ itself. Such a situation is a far cry from the optimism and grand vision that marked its launch. This paper is an attempt to understand the implications of the ongoing euro zone crisis and the factors that make it somewhat unique as the contradictions of a monetary union without a fiscal union are coming to fore. The paper shows that the crisis is not merely related to sovereign debt and bank financials but also rooted in the real economy with structural problems. The manner in which the crisis is dealt is likely to be of far reaching significance to Europe and to the rest of the world. The stage seems set for a change in the way in which the euro zone will need to manage its monetary, fiscal and financial system. The Euro Zone Crisis

  • 4. 4 Its dimensions and implications Over the last two years, the euro zone has been going through an agonizing debate over the handling of its own home grown crisis, now the ̳euro zone crisis‘. Starting from Greece, Ireland, Portugal, Spain and more recently Italy, these euro zone economies have witnessed a downgrade of the rating of their sovereign debt, fears of default and a dramatic rise in borrowing costs. These developments threaten other Euro zone economies and even the future of the Euro. Such a situation is a far cry from the optimism and grand vision that marked the launch of the Euro in 1999 and the relatively smooth passage it enjoyed thereafter. While the Euro zone may be forced to do what it takes, it is unlikely that the situation will soon return to business as usual on its own. Yet, this crisis is not a currency crisis in a classic sense. Rather, it is about managing economies in a currency zone and the economic and political tensions that arise from the fact that its constituents are moving at varying speeds, have dramatically different fiscal capacities and debt profiles but their feet are tied together with a single currency. Given the large economic weight of the euro zone in the globe, and regularity with which the crisis is spreading from one euro zone economy to the next, the stage for palliatives is over. The manner, in which the euro zone crisis is dealt this point onwards, is likely to be of far reaching significance to the world. This paper shows that the crisis is not merely of sovereign debt and bank financials but also rooted in the real economy with structural problems. The stage is set for a change in the manner in which the euro zone will have to manage its monetary, fiscal and financial system. This paper is an attempt to understand the implications of the euro zone crisis in the light of the developments subsequent to the creation of the euro. Starting with a background in section 2, the paper analyses the factors that make the euro zone crisis unique in section 3. Section 4 delineates the significance of the ongoing developments which is followed by a few concluding observations.
  • 5. 5 Section 2
 : The Euro Zone: A background On January 1, 1999 eleven European countries decided to denominate their currencies into a single currency. The European monetary union (EMU) was conceived earlier in 1988–89 by a committee consisting mainly of central bankers which led to the Maastricht Treaty in 1991. The treaty established budgetary and monetary rules for countries wishing to join the EMU - called the ―convergence criteria‖i. The criterion were designed to be a basis for qualifying for the EMU and pertained to the size of budget deficits, national debt, inflation, interest rates, and exchange rates. Denmark, Sweden, and the United Kingdom chose not to join from the inception. Figure 1. The Euro Zone, Source ECB The "Euro system" comprised the European Central Bank (ECB), with 11 central banks of participating States assuming the responsibility for monetary policy. A large part of Europe came to have the same currency much like the Roman Empire, but with a crucial difference. The members were sovereign countries with their own tax systems. Greece failed to qualify, but was later admitted on 1 January 2001. The ̳Euro‘
  • 6. 6 took the form of notes and coins in 2002, and replaced the domestic currencies. From eleven euro zone members in 1999, the number increased to 17 in 2011. Justification for the Euro: The overarching justification for the Euro was not merely economic, but political. A single currency was perceived as a symbol of political and social integration in the post WW II Europe and a catalyst for further integration in other spheres. At the micro level, the use of a common currency was expected to increase cross- border competition, integration and efficiency in the markets for goods, services and capital. These developments were expected to reduce transactions costs (Hämäläinen:1999). The underlying logic for economies to integrate and adopt a single currency was based largely on the Theory of Optimum Currency Areas (OCA)‘, pioneered in the seminal work of Robert Mundell (1961). At the macroeconomic level, a single monetary policy in the euro area was expected to be geared to price stability. According to the ECB, the monetary policy in the Euro system has been guided by two ―pillars‖. First, an inflation target broadly based on an assessment of future price developments and the risks to price stability in the euro area measured by the Harmonized Index of Consumer Prices (HICP) and second, a ―reference value‖— not a specific monetary target— for the growth of a broad monetary aggregate. The Euro system's commitment to price stability was expected to contribute to the long- term stability and credibility of the euro and promote its attractiveness as a trading and investment currency. In the long run, the development and integration of the euro area financial markets was expected to enhance the attractiveness of the euro. The Euro was also expected to become an important currency in the foreign exchange markets. Convergence, cohabitation and divergence: Since the euro came into existence in 1999, and later in the physical form in 2002, there remained some skepticism on its future as some members had failed to stay within the norms under the growth and stability pact. Nevertheless, the euro
  • 7. 7 area money and financial markets saw rapid changes with the introduction of a new currency. Bond markets that were segmented got integrated in short period. From 1999 to 2002, and then on, there was convergence in the yields on government bonds (figure 2a). Interest rate dispersion between the rates offered by different banks in also declined (Figure 2b). The dispersion of country short-term rates measured also reduced. Figure 2a Source: OECD data
  • 8. 8 Figure 2b Source: Eurostat data Increased competition, the establishment of common benchmarks and lower transaction costs led to narrowing of yield and spreads and market liquidity across borders. These changes were facilitated by the TARGETiv system that linked large-value national payments in the EU. Thus similar instruments traded in the different national markets came to be perceived as close substitutes. The convergence in interest rates meant a fall in nominal rates in the peripheral economies towards the lower German levels (figure-2a). Credibility of the monetary policy on price stability and the accompanying economic growth were seen as positive outcomes of a single market and a seemingly stable common currency. Credit growth surged as currency risk premium diminished and competition spurred financial innovations as financial institutions could borrow easily abroad (figure 3a). The growth in credit was concentrated in the housing sector. Construction and financial services grew rapidly thereby increasing macroeconomic vulnerability. While property prices boomed (figure 3b), the credit growth got translated into a buildup in debt.
  • 9. 9 Figure 3a, Source: IMF, IFS data Figure 3b Source: FT. com Faster growth hid the weakness in the fiscal system that got revealed with the worsening in the fiscal deficit and public debt (Annex table). Growth was also accompanied by a rise in demand for imports and, in turn, a larger current account deficit from 2003. The rise in the twin deficits (figure-4a and 4b) were financed largely through debt, especially, in the case of Greece. So long as growth was strong, it was hard to make out whether there had been an improvement in the fundamentals, or it was a bubble. Till 2005, the general growth
  • 10. 10 momentum was in place, perhaps waiting for a trigger. Figure 4a Source: Eurostat Figure 4b Source; Eurostat
  • 11. 11 Section 3
 : From Global crisis to the Euro zone crisis The global financial crisis in 2007–08 acted as the trigger that set the snow ball of debt rolling across Europe and in the euro zone as growth declined sharply (figure 5). The financial crisis led to disruption in financial intermediation. The credit boom from 2003 lasting till early 2007 was supported by falling interest rates. But from 2006, interest rates across euro zone started to diverge, marking out the weak from the strong economies (as shown in figure 2a). Excessive lending had left banks with bad debts and governments with large fiscal deficit and public debt in the peripheral economies (albeit of varying magnitudes).
  • 12. 12 Figure 5 Source: Eurostat In order to meet liquidity problem arising from financial crisis, on 11 October 2008, the EU held an extraordinary summit in Paris to define a joint action for the euro zone and agreed to a bank rescue plan to boost their finances and guarantee interbank lending. Coordination against the crisis was considered vital to prevent the actions of one country harming another and exacerbating bank solvency and credit shortage. The various emergency measures announced to counter financial crisis during 2008- 2009, appeared to have been successful in averting financial crisis and supporting short- term domestic demand. However, they aggravated fiscal deficit and debt. In late 2009, Greece admitted that its fiscal deficit was understated (12.7 % of GDP, as against 3.7 % stated earlier). Ratings agencies downgraded Greek bank and government debt. In late 2009, its public debt was over 113 % of GDP, far more that the euro zone limit of 60 %. A crisis of confidence due to high fiscal deficit and debt was marked by widening bond yields and risk insurance on credit default swaps. By early 2010, a sovereign debt crisis in the euro zone was clearly on hand with Greece in the eye of the storm. The problems of Ireland, Portugal and Spain were also out in the open. Even though, the configuration of fiscal deficit, public debt, private debt and bank lending across these
  • 13. 13 economies was considerably different, the financial markets passed a similar judgment through a rise in the CDS premiums, albeit differentiated (figure 6). After all, the global financial crisis had brought home an important lesson - that on the extreme, all private debt could potentially be public debt. Source: Datastream On 2 May 2010, to reassure investors confidence, the EU and IMF put together a €110bn bailout package for Greece conditional on implementation of austerity measures. This was followed on 9 May 2010 by a decision by 27 member states of the European Union to create the European Financial Stability Facility (EFSF), a special purpose vehicle, in order to help preserve financial stability in Europe by providing financial assistance to euro zone states in difficulty. The EFSF was empowered to sell bonds and use the money to make loans up to a maximum of € 440 billion to euro zone nations. The bonds were to be backed by guarantees given by the European Commission representing the whole EU, the euro zone member states, and the IMF. The EFSF combined the € 60 billion loan coming from the European financial stabilization mechanism (reliant on guarantees given by the European Commission using the EU budget as collateral) and a € 250 billion loan backed by the IMF in order to obtain a financial safety net up to € 750 billion. The agreement allowed the ECB to start buying government debt which was expected to reduce bond yields. As per the conditions, Greece
  • 14. 14 was to mobilize $ 70 billion by way of privatization of its state enterprises. In November, 2010 EU and IMF agree to bail-out the Irish Republic with 85bn Euros. The Irish Republic soon passes the toughest budget in the country's history. The measures taken in May 2010 had a palliative effect. Serious doubts remained on the ability of Greece to service its debt and bond yields started to spike again. In April 2011, Portugal admitted that it could not deal with its finances and asked the EU for help. In May 2011, European finance ministers approved euro 78 billion rescue loans to Portugal. Meanwhile, Moody‘s lowered Greece‘s credit rating to junk status on June 1 2011 (to Caa1 from B1). An extraordinary summit was again convened on 21 July 2011 in Brussels. The leaders decided to take measures to stop the risk of contagion. They agreed on a further bailout for Greece for 109billion euros with the participation of the IMF and voluntary contribution from the private sector in order to cover the financing gap. The EFSF was indicated as the financing vehicle for the disbursement with regular assessment by the Commission in liaison with the ECB and the IMF. The agreement included extending the loan repayment periods and a cut in interest rates. To prevent the possible contagion, the leaders agreed to increase the flexibility of the EFSF to be able to lend to states preventively on the basis of a precautionary programme. The EFSF was empowered to recapitalize financial institutions through loans to governments even in those countries that were not under any programme. Further the EFSF was allowed to intervene in the secondary markets to deal with exceptional financial market circumstances and in the event of a risk to financial stability. To increase fiscal consolidation and growth in the euro area, the 17 leaders pledged continued support to the countries successfully implementing their programmes. They agreed to apply to Portugal and Ireland the same EFSF lending conditions that they confirmed for Greece, i.e., extended debt maturities to a minimum of 15 years and reduced interest rate to around 3.5 %. It was agreed that all the euro area
  • 15. 15 member states would strictly adhere to the agreed fiscal targets. In addition to solving their eventual macro-economic imbalances, the member states (with the exception of those under a programme) are to reduce their deficits below 3 percent by 2013. As an additional measure, the leaders invited the European Investment Bank to help the countries receiving EU and IMF assistance in absorbing the funds. All these measures have so far failed to assuage the financial markets. The indications are that the financial markets continue to be deeply skeptical about their effectiveness. While Greece remains an extreme case, the problem of public and private debt (in varying proportions) in other peripheral economies like Ireland, Portugal, Spain and Italy are also a source of concern albeit with their own peculiarities. We recount some of the specificities of the problem faced in these economies before reverting to the overarching dimensions and implications of the euro zone crisis. Ireland: The case of Ireland has been marked by an almost whole sale nationalization of the banking sector that translated into severe fiscal stress. But not long back, the Ireland was hailed as the Celtic tiger for its economic dynamism. The economy expanded rapidly during 1997-2007 with investment stimulated, in part, due to a low corporate tax rates. With low interest rates, there was rapid expansion of credit and property valuations from 2002 to 2007. The rise in mortgages was accompanied by banks relying heavily on whole sale external borrowing. As property prices showed a downward movement from 2007 Irish banks stood exposed and came under severe pressure. The property price crash by the first half of 2009 broadly coincided with the tightening of credit control. By mid April 09, there was a marked increase in Irish bond yields and the government had to nationalize banks and take on the liabilitiesvi. In September 2010, government support for six banks had risen markedly to 32 per cent of GDP. In November 2010, the government decided to seek a €85 billion "bailout" from the ECB and the IMF. Thus the problems of Ireland stemmed from an excessive build up of bank lending rather than public debt as in the case of Greece. But, the banking crisis turned into a fiscal problem. In terms of unemployment, Ireland with an
  • 16. 16 unemployment rate of 13.7 percent is among the worst-affected, after Spain which also witnessed a collapse in the property sector. Spain, like Ireland, was considered a dynamic economy and till 2005 and attracted significant foreign investment. The economy witnessed a real estate boom with construction representing close to 16 per cent of GDP. This changed with the global crisis. In cumulative terms, housing prices fell significantly from 2007. As the real estate boom collapsed there was a rise in the levels of personal debt. On the public finances front, tax revenues collapsed, deficits soared and the budget position moved to a deficit of over 11 per cent in 2009 (Annex tables). Interest rates on lending to companies and other categories showed an upward turn and financing continued to decline indicating weakness of the economy. The one difference that marks out Spain is that its public debt at about 60 per cent of GDP (in 2010) is low by euro zone standards. But the problem is on account of foreign exposure to its private debt. The Spanish banks have relied heavily on whole sale finance from abroad. Spain also has a very high rate of unemployment in comparison to the rest of the euro zone. Unemployment among youth is particularly high in Spain and remains a potential source of unrest. Portugal: While the Financial Crisis affected the Portuguese economy on account of which its fiscal deficit and public debt deteriorated from -3.1 per cent and 68 per cent of GDP (in 2007) to -10 per cent and 83 percent in 2009, the down turn in GDP growth for Portugal was one of the mildest (only -2.5 %) compared to a sharper decline in the rest of the euro zone. Public debt and deficit is also lower than Greece. In that respect, the situation of Portugal is unlike the other peripheral economies that witnessed a boom-bust situation. Portugal, however, has a significantly large external current account deficit and external debt fuelled largely by private sector borrowing. In terms of other social indicators that are critical for productivity, Portugal ranks low. For instance, as per the OECD surveys, Portugal has one of the lowest percentage of population with at least upper secondary education in the age group of 25 to 64 as compared to the EU average.
  • 17. 17 Alongside, Portugal has also shown an increase in the structural rate of unemployment right from 2000. In other words, Portugal faces a somewhat different problem from some of the other peripheral economies, that is - of chronic low rate of growth. Italy: Italy is the eighth-largest economy in the world and the fourth- largest in Europe in terms of nominal GDP (in 2010). It has been a slow growth economy with GDP growth averaging just about 1 per cent per annum over 2000-07 as compared to close to 2 per cent for the euro zone. While its fiscal deficit at -4.6 per cent of GDP in 2010 is lower than the - 6 per cent for the euro zone, Italy‘s public debt and external debt ratios at 119 and 108 are rather large. Even though much of the public debt is held by its residents, it has large private tradable debt which makes it very difficult to rescue. While its unemployment rate at 8.4 per cent is lower than the average for the euro zone, Italy has always been characterized by north- south divide with the southern parts witnessing chronically high unemployment rates. An point to note is that there are significant differences in terms of the configuration of macroeconomic variables and structural differences (an aspect we discuss in the next section) across the euro zone economies that are currently in trouble. In Greece, the banks – which were reasonably strong on a ―stand-alone‖ basis were undone by revelations about the weakness of public finances. In Ireland, causation ran in an opposite direction with failing domestic banks imposing a burden on the fiscal position. Regardless of the causation, the consequences have been the same: as confidence eroded, the inflow of foreign capital dried up and public debt mounted. Nevertheless, the markets have been penalizing one economy after another, albeit to different degrees. And the contagion effect seems to be spreading. Are there some dimensions that make the euro zone crisis special? We turn to this question in the next section. Section 4
 : Some critical dimensions of the EZ crisis
  • 18. 18 By 2011, the euro zone crisis turned predominantly into a sovereign debt crisis intricately woven with bank debt and claims across borders within and outside the monetary union. In that respect, the euro zone problem is somewhat unique and sui generisvii. A monetary union without a fiscal union: The creation of the Euro zone had an inherent contradiction of being a monetary union but not a fiscal union. The introduction of the euro in 1999 explicitly prevented the ECB or any national central bank from financing government deficits. As a consequence the central bank has no power to monetize deficits. The above arrangement put a premium on each country to follow a similar fiscal path, but, without a common treasury to enforce it. The spending authorities remained national and subject to their own political compulsions. So long as growth across the region was strong, the fiscal capacity was not a source of worry. In such an arrangement the possibility of fiscal free riding is present as seen from the current episode for Greece. Given the differences in the structure and competitiveness of the peripheral economies, it is not surprising that their compliance to the growth and stability pact was often in breach. And this weakness got further exposed in the after math of the global crisis due to the operation of fiscal stabilizers, a rise in the unemployment compensation and a fall in tax revenues. The option of improving the competiveness of the economy through exchange rate depreciation was not available from the very inception of the monetary union. The EU budget is only 1 % of the EU GDP and not an effective instrument for fiscal stabilization. Had there been a fiscal union, with a system horizontal transfer and controls, the deficit and debt ratio of the peripheral economies may have been contained. But in the present case, a fiscal crisis in the periphery automatically translated into zonal monetary and financial crisis with the central monetary authority not empowered to act as the lender of last resort. This brings home an important lesson that setting up pacts and codes of conduct by themselves are not enough, unless, the underlying incentives
  • 19. 19 to adhere to them are also reasonably well aligned. It has also been argued that the fiscal criteria proved difficult to enforce but generated a false assurance that as long as there was a criteria, all was well. They failed to see that other structural problems were far more dangerous to economic stability of the euro zone that included the lack of control and regulation over national financial institutions (Pavoncello: 2011). Varying productivity and Structural differences: Within the euro zone, there is substantial variation in terms of productivity. The peripheral economies have lower labor productivity compared to Germany (taken as a bench mark of 100) which clearly stands out in terms of unit labour costs. Only France and Ireland are comparable to Germany on this count (figure 7a). Figure 7a Source: OECD The Global competitiveness index for the Euro zone countries also shows vast differences in terms of the ranking and score (annex table). On account of differences in the labor market conditions the unemployment rates are also vast divergent. As compared to the peripheral economies, Germany has the lowest rate of unemployment rate due to its short-time working scheme and flexible time arrangements in the manufacturing sector (Annex table and figure 6b). The fact that there has been a persistence different in the unemployment levels show
  • 20. 20 that labour mobility remained far more limited as compared capital mobility despite there being a monetary union. Figure 7b Source Eurostat The above differences in a currency union could get sharply exaggerated, as they did, when countries are subject to asymmetric shocks, or to put it the other way around, when their capacity to weather a similar shock is vastly different. Member countries cannot use the exchange rate adjustment to improve their competitiveness. Large fiscal deficit and public debt with interconnected and weak banking systems can then make matters worse if debt is held across borders which is an issue we deal with shortly. In the peripheral economies of the euro zone all these problems seem to have occurred in quick succession.
  • 21. 21 Role of cross border lending: The modest success of the euro had all along been crucially dependent on the ability of the constituent economies to maintain, or appear to maintain,
 fiscal discipline and the ability of
 the private sector and the financial
 services industry to retain the trust
 of the markets. Ironically, it is the integration in the financial and money markets, that in part, was due to a common currency, which makes the euro zone crisis harder to untangle. This foregoing integration is seen in terms of the large share of public debt held across borders (table 1) with European banks (German, French, British and others) having cross border exposure. Data from the Bank of International settlements gives an indication of the magnitude of exposure for major economies in the euro zone. Germany and France non euro economies like UK and US have substantial exposure to bank debt of the peripheral economies (Table 2). In respect of the US, the indirect exposure is several times larger than the direct exposure. The interlocking and conflicting interests of the holders of the liabilities of the peripheral euro zone economies thorough cross border holding of debt makes the resolution of the euro zone crisis furthermore difficult. Aggregate data, needs to be interpreted with caution, as the magnitude is not a direct indicator of the potential default, but only of the total exposure at a point in time, that too with incomplete coverage.
  • 22. 22 Nevertheless, given their large exposure, the European banks may find it difficult to wish away their engagement with the peripheral economies. Decision making system in
 the Euro zone: Even at the
 national level where there are
 sub national entities, decision
 making is always problematic.
 In the case of the Euro zone
 decisions on financial
 assistance requires unanimity
 among representatives of
 member states. In a monetary
 union, political decisions taken
 in one country affect the
 economies of other countries. Except for the ECB there are few organizations’ that have a euro zone wide view. But the ECB is a central bank with a limited focus on the macro- economy. But economic policies remain controlled by national governments with fiscal consequence.
  • 23. 23 Section 5
 : Implications of the EZC and possible directions The euro zone crisis has been moving from one peripheral economy to the next, and more recently, is affecting the core economies in the euro zone. The EU accounts for close to 26 per cent of the world GDP (at market exchange rates) and the euro zone 19.4 per cent. The Euro area accounts for about 10 per cent of the global equity markets turnover and the euro accounts for 26 percent of the allocated global holding of reserves. Thus the significance of this crisis is not merely that it comes in the aftermath of the global crisis, but more importantly, it threatens the pace of recovery of the global economy especially because the EU and within that, the Euro zone is a significant market for rest of the world. In its "spillover" report on the effects of euro zone policies on other major economies, the IMF observed that an intensification of the euro area debt crisis, especially if stress were to spread to the core economies could have major global consequences. In particular, if the Euro area core economies were to be affected. Banks throughout the euro zone immediately require more and higher quality capital. While capital raising and recapitalizing banks is needed, the report observes that in the short run, this may have a contractionary effect. But the critical question that arises in this context is where the resources for recapitalizing the banks will come from? Implications for the advanced countries: More than any part of the world, the manner in which the current crisis is dealt is important for the Euro zone and to Europe. The creation of the European Union and the euro zone has been part of the European dream of integration. A breakup of the euro would be painful in economic terms and in terms of its political fallout. A serious challenge is being faced by the two European giants Germany and France because the banks of both these countries face large
  • 24. 24 exposures as already indicated. The markets have been relentless in pricing them down. Even the United Kingdom, that technically remains outside the euro zone does not have the choice of remaining a passive spectator for the same reason as British banks also have a substantial exposure to debt in the troubled countries of the Euro zone. As at present, the United States has a large financial stake in Europe. American banks have over $600 billion of exposure in the troubled economies of the euro zone as per BIS data. There are close trading links as Europe is US’s largest trading partner and the largest destination for investment by U.S. corporations. Following the collapse of the Lehman brothers in 2008, the US opened short term loans to European banks. In 2009, the US Fed went in for the second round of quantitative easing by buying treasury bonds and pushing down long-term interest rates. By August 2011, its own debt position has become a matter of concern. The capacity of US to accommodate liquidity in order to support the euro zone economies, this time around may be more limited. The Euro zone crisis and the EMEs: The current crisis is important in terms of the current transition that is taking place globally in the geo political context. For both China and India, Europe and the euro zone accounts for a significant market. Therefore stagnation or worse, a downturn in the euro zone will dent their export growth. But in regard to China, the threats and the opportunities are somewhat interestingly balanced. China has been looking for opportunities to diversify its foreign exchange assets. The current situation provides China an opportunity to make bargains during a fire sale that may follow to gain political mileage and acquire useful and perhaps strategic assets by simply offering to hold troubled assets of the troubled euro zone States. These assets could be in the form of sovereign debt as well as real assets like interest in public sector units that may be privatized. The manner in which the euro zone and the EU would respond to this possibility remains to be seen.
  • 25. 25 As far as India is concerned, the European Union is a major trade partner accounting for as much as 20.2 per cent of India’s exports (in 2009-10) and 13.3 per cent of India’s imports. European Union countries imported roughly € 33.1 billion worth of Agriculture products, Fuel and mining products, machinery and transport equipment, chemicals, semi manufactured products textile and clothing products in 2010 from India. The EU exports to India amounted to €34.8bl, majority of which was machinery, chemical products and semi manufactured items which was almost 2.6 percent of EU exports. Bilateral trade between the two has been growing on an average of 9.6 per cent during 2006-10. EU services exports to India during 2010 was €9.8 billion and EU imports from India was €8.1 billion. That apart, the total FDI from EU during 2010 amounted to €3.0 billion while India also invested about €0.6 billion in the EU. In other words, a slowdown in the euro zone and the EU is likely to have a major adverse impact on India’s exports. Apart from trade, the euro zone experience has some lessons for India. Whole sale debt funding has been the unmaking for banks in the Euro zone. While it is difficult to argue that banks should only raise debt resources through retail deposits, at the same time, the current episode shows that large scale reliance on whole sale debt, especially, from across borders may not be in the interest of financial stability. In this context, the Indian banking system has traditionally relied on retail deposits which despite higher cost; serve as a stable source of funding. Without necessarily shunning the option, any substantial shift towards whole sale debt funding may not be a desirable. India, despite its high fiscal deficit and debt has the advantage of public debt being passively held in bank portfolios. This practice has continued hitherto as a vestige of the era of financial repression. While there is every reason to maintain prudence in public finance, at a given point, this EZ experience raises the question of whether sovereign debt of a country can be held largely outside a country in portfolios that keep getting churned and subject to day-to-day re-pricing. This issue is important since sovereign debt, unlike corporate debt, is meant to finance long- term development.
  • 26. 26 The global financial crisis demonstrated that the globalized banking system played a crucial role in transmitting the crisis from the advanced economies to various parts of the world, including the emerging markets. The current crisis also bears lessons for making a choice on the manner in which foreign banks operating in emerging economies should be allowed by the regulators to expand, that is, through the route of subsidiaries or through branches. Possible directions: For dealing with the EZ crisis, the possible alternatives being debated are on three broad lines. The first is the route of austerity, in particular, fiscal consolidation, including privatization. This is the default policy choice. A forgone conclusion is that this will impose social costs. While fiscal consolidation is desirable, the question is whether, at all, this choice will lead to sustained growth in the near future, since the compression at this juncture would be extreme. Real growth is stagnating and prospects of exports leading growth appear dim. The peripheral economies are subject to a large mismatch between revenues and expenditure at the level of the government and at the household level leading to unsustainable governments and private debt. The possibility that these economies will grow themselves out of the problem seems remote. In any case, this choice does not address the structural problems faced in the peripheral economies. Therefore, the current strategy of announcing short term palliatives such as further bail outs along with sharp fiscal consolidation may only prolong the agony but not deal with the uncertainty prevailing in the euro zone. The second option, (rather an imperative), would be to go in for a closer fiscal union and a substantially enlarged European budget with a limited system of fiscal transfers from rich countries to the poor countries, a common form of protection for employment on the German lines with more flexibility, greater cross border investment even if this implies takeover of sick and ailing public sector units by companies from the richer Euro zone states. A further step would then be to move the ECB into the role of a proper central banker and then floating euro bonds.
  • 27. 27 EMES is a research network of established university research centres and individual researchers whose goal is to gradually build up a European corpus of theoretical and empirical knowledge, pluralistic in disciplines and methodology, around “Third Sector” issues. A fiscal union, if that be the future road, between what are clearly a few strong and other weaker economies is going to be a major political and economic challenge. In light of the experience thus far, it may be necessary to build an institutional framework that permits a multi speed Europe rather than hoping for complete convergence that breaks down in times of stress. Ironically, in the event of a fiscal union materializing, Germany will face a daunting challenge of supporting a large part of the transfers. Germany has been through a similar, (if not the same) experience, the most recent being the experience of German unification where the country had to set up the Treuhandanstalt†, step up fiscal transfers and absorb a large and a substantially poorer labor force. It was successful. The process culminated in the adoption of the 2010 plan and Germany bouncing back as the economic power house of Europe. But as of now, this option is hardly finding favor in the big two (Germany and France) due to the fiscal burden that may befall them. Notwithstanding the political challenges en route, a creditable road map towards fiscal union will undoubtedly be a challenge and require considerable groundwork. The third option is the radical one, of peripheral economies leaving the euro zone. A breakdown of the currency may be a very expensive proposition. But if that were to happen, it could lead to insolvency of several Euro zone countries, a breakdown in intra zone payments. Given that public debt in these countries is present in the balance sheets of banks and insurance companies across the world, contagion effects and instability could spread through the financial system. In comparison, the sub-prime crisis may almost pale into insignificance (Pagano, 2010, Eichengreen 2007). This outcome also means an end of the European dream.
  • 28. 28 † An agency set up to privatize East German enterprises Concluding observations: The outcome of the current crisis may be a matter of conjecture. As we have argued, the options, if at all, before the Euro zone and indeed the EU are very stark. None of the three choices are simple. Status quo is also not an option. The choices will have to be political, but the consequences will undoubtedly be economic. The issue is not any more on how to deal with the current crisis. Rather, to make the choice on ‘The Euro’ – as Eichengreen put it, to ‘love it or to leave it’ and depending on that, to do what needs to done. In the end, we conclude by observing that neither of these two roads would be easy, the one that carries with it the vision of unification still holds a dream but the other route may only take the euro economies further apart.
  • 29. 29 Selected References: a) EU (2011) European Union Statement by the heads of State or Government of the Euro Area and EU Institutions, Brussels, 21 July. b) Eichengreen Barry (2010) Euro, Love it or leave it, VOX, May 2010, accessed on9 August, 2011, http://www.voxeu.org c) Eichengreen Barry (2008) The Breakup of the Euro Area, NBER Working Paper No. 13393, University of California, Berkeley d) IMF (2011) Euro Area Policies: Spillover Report 2011, Washington DC, Acessed on 12 August, 2011. http://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/scr/2011/cr11185.pdf e) Lorenzo Bini Smaghi (2011): Eurozone, European crisis and policy responses, Speech by Member of the Executive Board of the European Central Bank, at the Goldman Sachs Global Macro Conference – Asia 2011, Hong Kong, 22 February 2011. http://www.bis.org/review/ f) Mundell (1961) "A Theory of Optimum Currency Areas". American Economic Review 51 (4): 657–665. g) Sirkka Hämäläinen (1999) The euro: the birth of a new currency, Presentation by, Member, Executive Board of the European Central Bank, at the meeting of the Institute International d' Etudes Bancaires on 21 May 1999,Helsinki,http://www.ecb.int/press/key/date/1999/html/sp990521.en.htm l h) OECD, Education at a Glance 2009: OECD indicators i) Pagano Marco (2010) Fiscal crisis, contagion, and the future of euro, VOX, 15 May, http://www.voxeu.org/index.php?q=node/5041
  • 30. 30 j) Pavoncello Franco (2011) One for all, All for one, The Euro crisis, World Affairs, May-June. Annex tables Growth in GDP – Selected euro zone economies 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 Euro area 1.9 0.9 0.8 2.2 1.7 3.1 2.8 0.4 -4.2 1.8 Germany 1.2 0.0 -0.2 1.2 0.8 3.4 2.7 1.0 -4.7 3.6 France 1.8 0.9 0.9 2.5 1.8 2.5 2.3 -0.1 -2.7 1.5 Ireland 5.7 6.5 4.4 4.6 6.0 5.3 5.6 -3.5 -7.6 -1.0 Greece 4.2 3.4 5.9 4.4 2.3 5.2 4.3 1.0 -2.0 -4.5 Spain 3.6 2.7 3.1 3.3 3.6 4.0 3.6 0.9 -3.7 -0.1 Italy 1.8 0.5 0.0 1.5 0.7 2.0 1.5 -1.3 -5.2 1.3 Portugal 2.0 0.7 -0.9 1.6 0.8 1.4 2.4 0.0 -2.5 1.3 Source: Eurostat Fiscal Deficit and public debt to GDP ratio (%) 2001 2002 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 Fiscal Deficit / GDP (%) Euro area -17 -1.9 -2.6 -2.5 -1.4 -0.7 -2.0 -6.3 -6.0 Germany -2.8 -3.7 -3.3 -1.6 0.3 0.1 -3.0 -3.3 France -1.5 -3.1 -2.9 -2.3 -2.7 -3.3 -7.5 -7.0 Ireland 0.9 -0.4 1.6 2.9 0.1 -7.3 -14.3 -32.4 Greece -4.5 -4.8 -5.2 -5.7 -6.4 -9.8 -15.4 -10.5 Spain -0.6 -0.5 1.0 2.0 1.9 -4.2 -11.1 -9.2 Italy -3.1 -2.9 -4.3 -3.4 -1.5 -2.7 -5.4 -4.6 Portugal -4.3 -2.9 -5.9 -4.1 -3.1 -3.5 -10.1 -9.1 Public debt / GDP (%) Euro area- 17 68.1 67.9 70 68.4 66.2 69.9 79.3 85.1 Germany 58.8 60.4 68 67.6 64.9 66.3 73.5 83.2 France 56.9 58.8 66.4 63.7 63.9 67.7 78.3 81.7 Ireland 35.5 32.1 27.4 24.8 25.0 44.4 65.6 96.2 Greece 103.7 101.7 100 106.1 105.4 110.7 127.1 142.8 Spain 55.5 52.5 43 39.6 36.1 39.8 53.3 60.1 Italy 108.8 105.7 105.9 106.6 103.6 106.3 116.1 119 Portugal 51.2 53.8 62.8 63.9 68.3 71.6 83.0 93.0 Source: Eurostat Annex tables External debt as ratio of GDP Greece Ireland Spain Portugal Italy 2007 97 535 110 118 92 Growth in GDP – Selected euro zone economies 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 Euro area 1.9 0.9 0.8 2.2 1.7 3.1 2.8 0.4 -4.2 1.8 Germany 1.2 0.0 -0.2 1.2 0.8 3.4 2.7 1.0 -4.7 3.6 France 1.8 0.9 0.9 2.5 1.8 2.5 2.3 -0.1 -2.7 1.5 Ireland 5.7 6.5 4.4 4.6 6.0 5.3 5.6 -3.5 -7.6 -1.0 Greece 4.2 3.4 5.9 4.4 2.3 5.2 4.3 1.0 -2.0 -4.5 Spain 3.6 2.7 3.1 3.3 3.6 4.0 3.6 0.9 -3.7 -0.1 Italy 1.8 0.5 0.0 1.5 0.7 2.0 1.5 -1.3 -5.2 1.3 Portugal 2.0 0.7 -0.9 1.6 0.8 1.4 2.4 0.0 -2.5 1.3 Source: Eurostat Fiscal Deficit and public debt to GDP ratio (%) 2001 2002 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 Fiscal Deficit / GDP (%) Euro area -17 -1.9 -2.6 -2.5 -1.4 -0.7 -2.0 -6.3 -6.0 Germany -2.8 -3.7 -3.3 -1.6 0.3 0.1 -3.0 -3.3 France -1.5 -3.1 -2.9 -2.3 -2.7 -3.3 -7.5 -7.0 Ireland 0.9 -0.4 1.6 2.9 0.1 -7.3 -14.3 -32.4 Greece -4.5 -4.8 -5.2 -5.7 -6.4 -9.8 -15.4 -10.5 Spain -0.6 -0.5 1.0 2.0 1.9 -4.2 -11.1 -9.2 Italy -3.1 -2.9 -4.3 -3.4 -1.5 -2.7 -5.4 -4.6 Portugal -4.3 -2.9 -5.9 -4.1 -3.1 -3.5 -10.1 -9.1 Public debt / GDP (%) Euro area- 17 68.1 67.9 70 68.4 66.2 69.9 79.3 85.1 Germany 58.8 60.4 68 67.6 64.9 66.3 73.5 83.2 France 56.9 58.8 66.4 63.7 63.9 67.7 78.3 81.7 Ireland 35.5 32.1 27.4 24.8 25.0 44.4 65.6 96.2 Greece 103.7 101.7 100 106.1 105.4 110.7 127.1 142.8 Spain 55.5 52.5 43 39.6 36.1 39.8 53.3 60.1 Italy 108.8 105.7 105.9 106.6 103.6 106.3 116.1 119 Portugal 51.2 53.8 62.8 63.9 68.3 71.6 83.0 93.0 Source: Eurostat
  • 31. 31 20 External debt as ratio of GDP Greece Ireland Spain Portugal Italy 2007 97 535 110 118 92 2008 139 697 68 182 43 Italy 108.8 105.7 105.9 106.6 103.6 106.3 116.1 119 Portugal 51.2 53.8 62.8 63.9 68.3 71.6 83.0 93.0 Source: Eurostat 2009 154 1041 158 207 110 2010 181 1121 171 221 108 Unemployment rate, annual average (%) Euro area 16 8.1 8.5 8.9 9.0 9.2 8.5 7.6 7.6 9.6 10 Germany 7.6 8.4 9.3 9.8 11.2 10.3 8.7 7.5 7.8 7 Ireland 3.9 4.5 4.6 4.5 4.4 4.5 4.6 6.3 11.9 13 Greece 10.7 10.3 9.7 10.5 9.9 8.9 8.3 7.7 9.5 12 Spain 10.3 11.1 11.1 10.6 9.2 8.5 8.3 11.3 18.0 20 Italy 9.1 8.6 8.4 8.0 7.7 6.8 6.1 6.7 7.8 8 Portugal 4.6 5.7 7.1 7.5 8.6 8.6 8.9 8.5 10.6 12 Source: Eurostat Ranking of Euro Area in the Global Competitiveness Index 2010–2011 Sub Indexes Country/ Economy OVERALL INDEX Basic requirements Efficiency enhancers Innovation and sophistication factors Rank Score Rank Score Rank Score Rank Score many 5 5.39 6 5.89 13 5.11 5 5.51 and 7 5.37 5 5.97 14 5.09 6 5.43 herlands 8 5.33 9 5.82 8 5.24 8 5.16 nce 15 5.13 16 5.67 15 5.09 16 4.83 tria 18 5.09 15 5.67 19 4.83 13 4.97 ium 19 5.07 22 5.45 17 5.01 15 4.91 embourg 20 5.05 10 5.81 20 4.92 19 4.76 and 29 4.74 35 5.18 25 4.68 21 4.55 nia 33 4.61 25 5.38 34 4.52 45 3.90 rus 40 4.50 29 5.28 36 4.46 36 4.07 n 42 4.49 38 5.13 32 4.56 41 3.96 enia 45 4.42 34 5.18 46 4.33 35 4.08 ugal 46 4.38 42 5.01 43 4.36 39 3.98 y 48 4.37 46 4.84 45 4.33 32 4.11 ta 50 4.34 40 5.08 47 4.31 46 3.88 ak Republic 60 4.25 53 4.77 37 4.43 63 3.54 ece 83 3.99 67 4.49 59 4.12 73 3.41 rce: Global Competitiveness Report 2010–2011, World Economic forum 2009 154 1041 158 207 110 2010 181 1121 171 221 108 Unemployment rate, annual average (%) Euro area 16 8.1 8.5 8.9 9.0 9.2 8.5 7.6 7.6 9.6 10.1 Germany 7.6 8.4 9.3 9.8 11.2 10.3 8.7 7.5 7.8 7.1 Ireland 3.9 4.5 4.6 4.5 4.4 4.5 4.6 6.3 11.9 13.7 Greece 10.7 10.3 9.7 10.5 9.9 8.9 8.3 7.7 9.5 12.6 Spain 10.3 11.1 11.1 10.6 9.2 8.5 8.3 11.3 18.0 20.1 Italy 9.1 8.6 8.4 8.0 7.7 6.8 6.1 6.7 7.8 8.4 Portugal 4.6 5.7 7.1 7.5 8.6 8.6 8.9 8.5 10.6 12.0 Source: Eurostat Ranking of Euro Area in the Global Competitiveness Index 2010–2011 Sub Indexes Country/ Economy OVERALL INDEX Basic requirements Efficiency enhancers Innovation and sophistication factors Rank Score Rank Score Rank Score Rank Score Germany 5 5.39 6 5.89 13 5.11 5 5.51 Finland 7 5.37 5 5.97 14 5.09 6 5.43 Netherlands 8 5.33 9 5.82 8 5.24 8 5.16 France 15 5.13 16 5.67 15 5.09 16 4.83 Austria 18 5.09 15 5.67 19 4.83 13 4.97 Belgium 19 5.07 22 5.45 17 5.01 15 4.91 Luxembourg 20 5.05 10 5.81 20 4.92 19 4.76 Ireland 29 4.74 35 5.18 25 4.68 21 4.55 Estonia 33 4.61 25 5.38 34 4.52 45 3.90 Cyprus 40 4.50 29 5.28 36 4.46 36 4.07 Spain 42 4.49 38 5.13 32 4.56 41 3.96 Slovenia 45 4.42 34 5.18 46 4.33 35 4.08 Portugal 46 4.38 42 5.01 43 4.36 39 3.98 Italy 48 4.37 46 4.84 45 4.33 32 4.11 Malta 50 4.34 40 5.08 47 4.31 46 3.88 Slovak Republic 60 4.25 53 4.77 37 4.43 63 3.54
  • 32. 32 21 Ranking of Euro Area in the Global Competitiveness Index 2010–2011 Sub Indexes Country/ Economy OVERALL INDEX Basic requirements Efficiency enhancers Innovation and sophistication factors Rank Score Rank Score Rank Score Rank Score Germany 5 5.39 6 5.89 13 5.11 5 5.51 Finland 7 5.37 5 5.97 14 5.09 6 5.43 Netherlands 8 5.33 9 5.82 8 5.24 8 5.16 France 15 5.13 16 5.67 15 5.09 16 4.83 Austria 18 5.09 15 5.67 19 4.83 13 4.97 Belgium 19 5.07 22 5.45 17 5.01 15 4.91 Luxembourg 20 5.05 10 5.81 20 4.92 19 4.76 Ireland 29 4.74 35 5.18 25 4.68 21 4.55 Estonia 33 4.61 25 5.38 34 4.52 45 3.90 Cyprus 40 4.50 29 5.28 36 4.46 36 4.07 Spain 42 4.49 38 5.13 32 4.56 41 3.96 Slovenia 45 4.42 34 5.18 46 4.33 35 4.08 Portugal 46 4.38 42 5.01 43 4.36 39 3.98 Italy 48 4.37 46 4.84 45 4.33 32 4.11 Malta 50 4.34 40 5.08 47 4.31 46 3.88 Slovak Republic 60 4.25 53 4.77 37 4.43 63 3.54 Greece 83 3.99 67 4.49 59 4.12 73 3.41 Source: Global Competitiveness Report 2010–2011, World Economic forum
  • 33. 33
  • 35. 35 Endnotes i As per the convergence criteria, countries had to keep budget deficit below 3% of GDP, public debt below 60%, maintain price stability and ensure interest rates remained within limits for at least 2 yrs to gain admittance to EMU. ii The euro zone currently consists of Austria, Belgium, Cyprus, Estonia, Finland, France, Germany, Greece, Ireland, Italy, Luxembourg, Malta, the Netherlands, Portugal, Slovakia, Slovenia, and Spain iii The success of the Marshall Plan led visionaries like Monnet, Schuman and others to push new cooperative initiatives like the creation of the European coal and steel community followed by the Treaty of Rome in 1957 which led to the setting up of the Common Market and spurred growth in Europe. iv Trans-European Automated Real-time Gross Settlement Express Transfer (TARGET) system) is an interbank and cross-border payment systemin the EU. v The targeted privatizations include prime tourist real estate, national gambling monopoly, Post bank, Athens and Thessaloniki ports, Water and Sewer Company and the telephone company. vi Between Jan 2009 to March 2009 the Irish government had to nationalise the Anglo Irish Bank, the Allied Irish Bank and the Bank of Ireland. These developments were linked to serious lapses in legal compliance also termed as circular lending (also termed as the Golden circle lending). vii In political science, the unparalleled development of the EU as compared to other international organizations has led to its designation as a sui generis geopolitical entity. The same could be said about the euro zone.
 viii Other factors not under control include the expansion of social benefits and the level of productivity. ix There has already been political fallout of the current crisis in the peripheral euro zone economies in terms of public unrest in Greece, Italy and to some extent in Spain. At least two finance ministers have been sacked one in Greece and the other in Italy with the latest fall out being the resignation of the board member of the ECB.
  • 36. 36 FREQUENTLY ASKED QUESTIONS: 1. What is Euro Debt Crisis ? 2. Can a country leave the euro? 3. What would be the likely trigger for a country leaving the euro? 4. Could a country default and stay within the euro? 5. Would an exit by one country (such as Greece) cause others to leave the euro? 6. Which countries would be most likely to stay in the euro, and which would be most likely to leave? 7. What would be the immediate economic and financial consequences for countries leaving the euro? 8. And for the countries that stayed? 
 9. What would be the impact on global financial markets?
 10. What would be the impact on the euro in relation to global currencies? 11. Would a global recession be inevitable if the euro collapsed?
 12. What would happen to banks in countries that left the euro?
 13. Could private debt in euros be enforced?
 14. What would happen to sovereign debt?
 15. Could EU internal market rules be maintained?
 16. Would countries that exited the euro remain in the EU?
 17. What levels of social and political upheaval would be expected?
 18. What should businesses do now?
  • 37. 37 1. What is Eurozone debt Crisis? The Eurozone Debt Crisis is an economic crisis due to the collapse of financial institutions, high government debt, and rapidly rising bond yield spreads in government securities faced by several European countries. The European sovereign debt crisis started in 2008, with the collapse of Iceland's banking system, and spread primarily to Greece, Ireland and Portugal during 2009. This led to a crisis of confidence for European businesses and economies. 2. Can a country leave the euro? Technically, no. However, we assume that under extreme circumstances, procedural and legal obstacles would not prevent an exit. No formal mechanism exists for a country to be expelled from the euro area or to leave of its own volition, and a comprehensively negotiated exit—if even possible—could take years. Instead, a country might leave unilaterally, breaching many of its legal obligations to the EU, its creditors and others. In this messy scenario, uncertainty in the interim over a country’s formal membership status would quickly become secondary to its de facto status as a pariah. Alternatively, a stricken country could in effect be expelled if policy institutions and fellow euro members decided to withhold financial support, thus pushing the country towards a position in which it felt unilateral exit was its best choice. The practical challenge of switching rapidly to a new currency—countries had years to prepare for the introduction of the euro—would also be formidable. 3. What would be the likely trigger for a country leaving the euro? It is conceivable but highly unlikely that Germany or another fiscally and economically strong country might decide to leave the euro. The more likely eventuality, which we examine here, is that of a
 weak economy such as Greece leaving. The most likely initial trigger would be a disorderly sovereign default. This could happen if the country refused to accept harsh terms for financial support; or if euro institutions, the IMF and other euro members declined to intervene further on the grounds that the country was failing to implement effective deficit-cutting measures. The former is most
  • 38. 38 likely. Default would wreak havoc in the domestic banking system because of banks’ sovereign debt exposure. In fear of bank failures, panic withdrawal of funds could follow. Unless countered by the provision of sufficient liquidity from the European Central Bank (ECB), this would in effect lead to the collapse of the banking system, making normal commercial life impossible. At this point, the only way to restart commercial activity could be to introduce a new national currency. 4. Could a country default and stay within the euro? A default would not automatically imply exit. A country could stay within the euro if sufficient institutional support and external financing for its banks were forthcoming. (Fears of systemic contagion, indeed, could make such support more likely.) The biggest factor would be whether the necessary political will existed inside the country, among its euro partners and from the “troika” of the ECB, European Commission and IMF. We believe that the costs of abandoning the single currency would far outweigh the benefits, such as currency depreciation that promoted export competitiveness. However, populist politics and/or opposition from an austerity-fatigued public to further painful cutbacks could create conditions in which the argument for leaving the euro appeared persuasive. 5.Would an exit by one country (such as Greece) cause others to leave the euro? There is a major risk that it would. For example, if Greece left the euro, the market pressures on
 the countries perceived as the next most vulnerable would rapidly become overwhelming. Bond
 yields would skyrocket, making funding from private markets unaffordable, even on the (generous) assumption that markets remained willing to lend at exorbitant rates. In one sense, such sovereign funding issues would not immediately matter for countries such as Portugal and Ireland, which are supported by a programme agreement with the European Financial Stability Facility (EFSF) and IMF. However, it is likely that these countries’ banking sectors would also come under increasing pressure amid heightened liquidity and solvency fears, raising immediate funding concerns and possibly triggering runs on deposits. These pressures could ultimately exceed the willingness of official institutions to intervene. In the case of countries without fiscal support programmes, the ECB and EFSF could either choose or feel compelled to
  • 39. 39 intervene, but they might not be able to do so on a sufficient scale to calm the markets. In both cases, the same process of collapse of the banking system leading
 to a political decision to exit the euro would then risk being repeated. The danger is that with each cycle, a bigger and harder-to-save economy would come under pressure, reducing the chances of policy success. It is worth noting that the chronology of contagion would be untidy. During the exit process, severe market pressures would already be present in other countries as investors priced in the anticipated impact. As the chain reaction spread across Europe, we think contagion would be rapid, dramatic and uncontrollable at times, but there might also be periods in which events moved slowly. For example, in the case of Italy, it would take time for higher interest costs on newly issued debt to increase the total interest burden to an unaffordable level. Every escalation of the crisis could also inspire greater official commitment to saving the euro, which would calm markets temporarily. 6. Which countries would be most likely to stay in the euro, and which would be most likely to leave? Firm predictions are tricky, but broadly a fracture between a strong northern “core” and the weaker “periphery” looks most likely. The process would, in our view, probably entail periphery countries breaking off individually to leave a “rump” of northern countries still within a currency union. Once one peripheral country (say, Greece) left, all the other vulnerable countries would probably follow. This means that Portugal, Ireland, Italy and Spain would leave the euro, although not necessarily immediately. Malta would probably leave, and Cyprus would have little choice but to exit as its banking system would be nearly wiped out by a Greek collapse. Up to ten countries could remain members of the euro: Germany, France, Austria, Belgium, Finland, Luxembourg, the Netherlands, Slovakia, Slovenia and Estonia (the last three all being small, open economies like Malta and Cyprus, but with healthier fundamentals). France’s status would be key. With memories of the speculative attacks and devaluations of the 1970s and 1980s still fresh in policymakers’ minds, no appetite whatsoever exists in the political mainstream for a return to a national currency. France would therefore make every effort to stay in the euro. However, a slimmed-down northern core would cause dramatic
  • 40. 40 currency appreciation that would make it difficult for France, with its external deficit rising as a result, to remain viable in the euro. Nevertheless, we think that monetary union with Germany is so fundamental to France’s view of its political and economic interests that it would be determined to stay, and that Germany would be willing to provide extensive financial support to enable France to do so. For Germany, close co- operation with France is a more fundamental part of its political culture than that with the peripheral countries. If France stayed, the new bloc could still be considered a smaller euro zone; if it left, the result would in effect be an enlarged D-mark zone. 7. What would be the immediate economic and financial consequences for countries leaving the euro? The consequences would be numerous and unpleasant. In anticipation of the euro exit, an accelerating bank run would be likely, as institutions and individuals rushed to move their deposits out of the country. This would severely threaten the banking system and would have to be halted by a prolonged bank holiday and/or capital controls. While bank withdrawals were frozen, the government would legislate to create a new currency. It would redenominate existing bank assets and liabilities into the new currency, and new banknotes and coins would be created. The new currency would depreciate dramatically against existing global currencies. Any debt that remained in euros would be much higher in local-currency terms. So too would debt in other currencies such as US dollars. The result would be massive balance-sheet problems, and many companies would become insolvent. External funding would also be cut off. Public-sector salaries and most private-sector salaries would have to be paid in the new currency. The country would suffer a sharp compression of imports, to the point where it could only import goods and services up to the value of hard currency it earned through exports. New trade contracts would have to be denominated in external currencies, as suppliers would want payments in strong currencies. If the introduction of a new currency had been preceded by sovereign default, this would mitigate
 the debt-servicing burden. However, any government that had not previously achieved a primary fiscal surplus would either have to implement further austerity (which would be deeply unpopular)
 or monetise the deficit, which, added to massive currency depreciation, would be highly
  • 41. 41 inflationary. Exiting from the euro would not in the short term prevent savage recession. At some point in the future, the country might be able to begin to return to sustainable growth on the basis of regained competitive advantage, although the difficulty of achieving the necessary internal adjustment could be formidable. In any event, successful economic reconstruction would only occur if wages could be reduced in real terms and efforts to compensate for inflation resisted. Recession in the rest of the euro zone would deplete demand for the departed country’s exports even after currency depreciation. Even under this grim general scenario, some economies would fare better than others. For example, Italy’s well-established export-manufacturing base and reasonably sound economic fundamentals (domestic debt aside) would mitigate the damage. Greece, in contrast, lacks a strong industrial base and would have little in the way of a functioning economy to fall back on. 8. And for the countries that stayed? The stronger northern core would suffer in three main ways. The most immediate and dramatic impact of a fracturing of the euro zone would be massive losses on domestic bank lending to governments and companies in the countries that had left. This would require major public intervention, possibly on an even larger scale than in 2008. In turn, this would add considerably to sovereign debt levels in Germany, France and elsewhere. Second, sharp currency appreciation would erode export competitiveness. Third, export demand in neighboring countries, particularly those whose currencies had depreciated, would collapse. This would have a serious impact, given the importance of trade between euro members. For example, Germany sent 41% of its exports to other euro area countries in 2010. For Austria, the corresponding figure was 54%. In both cases, the “weak” countries accounted for much lower shares of exports. However, a break-up of the euro would also cause recession in the stronger core and undermine global demand, so the overall downturn in exports would be substantial. 9. What would be the impact on global financial markets? Again, this would depend on the nature and scale of the break-up, but it would certainly be negative for equities and other risk assets, resulting in flight to safety on a potentially epic scale. Stock markets would fall dramatically in most countries. Although investors have already priced in
  • 42. 42 substantial negative expectations, a euro break-up would have a much more dramatic impact on confidence. Government bond markets would probably be split between those seen as relative safe havens and the rest. US bond yields could fall even further as investors piled into the “risk off” trade. German bunds could also benefit similarly, although this would depend on market perceptions of Germany’s success in isolating itself from weaker euro members. As in the aftermath of the collapse of Lehman Brothers in 2008, dislocations in the short-term markets that lubricate the global financial system would emerge. In Europe, the impact of break-up would probably surpass the turmoil seen in the wake of Lehman’s collapse. The potential fallout elsewhere in the world is difficult to judge, but with each new country that left the monetary union, the impact would become more severe. For example, departure and default
 by Italy—the world’s third- largest government bond issuer, with bonds worth about US$2.1trn in circulation—would immediately imperil the solvency of financial services companies across the world. Those that could not raise sufficient funds to compensate—a foreseeable problem given that liquidity would be tight— would have to turn to governments for support. The resultant market turmoil could be exacerbated by limited capacity for states to support the financial sector on a similar scale to that in 2008-09. 10. What would be the impact on the euro in relation to global currencies? Throughout the initial stages of break-up, the downward forces on the euro would be severe. If the ECB, for example, vastly expanded its bond-buying programme—in effect mimicking the US Federal Reserve’s quantitative easing—in an attempt to contain the crisis, the euro could drop sharply. The potentially lengthy limbo period during the break-up would also be highly negative for the single currency, owing to safe-haven factors. Money would flood into the dollar and potentially into other currencies such as the Swiss franc. However, if the situation stabilised, the rump euro would be a strong currency since it would contain only healthier northern economies. The euro would also benefit from the poor fundamentals of the US dollar, which have been masked by other factors until now.
  • 43. 43 11. Would a global recession be inevitable if the euro collapsed? A break-up would cause a deep recession throughout what is now the euro zone. Demand would weaken because of a combination of consumer retrenchment, higher unemployment, reduced spending power in countries that suffered sharp currency depreciation, and weaker exports. At the same time, the need for austerity would make substantial fiscal stimulus unaffordable in most west European countries. We also think serious disruption in the euro area would tip the US into recession. Moreover, even if the euro area avoids outright break-up, the uncertainty over the future of the single currency and associated economic weakness could still have a significant impact on US and global growth. US exports to the current euro area, which account for about 14% of the total, would suffer badly. There would also be a negative wealth effect as a result of sharp falls in US equity prices, which would hit US consumer spending. A renewed credit crunch driven by severe strains on the financial system would further limit the economy’s ability to expand. Other economies, including fast-growing emerging markets like China, would also be seriously affected. The EU is a major market for many export-oriented developing countries. Moreover, China is not in a position to match the scale of the stimulus package that it deployed in response to the global crisis of 2008-09—although the government would still be able to launch a substantial stimulus, and the approach of a major leadership transition in 2012-13 would make the Chinese Communist Party particularly keen to ensure that the economy continues to grow rapidly. It is also worth stressing that China is not as reliant on exports to drive economic growth as it was in 2008-09. Nevertheless, Chinese growth would clearly be hit if the euro zone broke up or went into depression. 12. What would happen to banks in countries that left the euro? There would be widespread insolvencies. A run on banks in the countries considered close to leaving the euro would be one of the likeliest triggers to make an exit reality. As the possibility of a euro exit—and inevitable devaluation of a new national currency—became more credible, depositors would rightly transfer their euros to banks in other countries. To a certain
  • 44. 44 extent, this is already happening across the euro area’s periphery. An acceleration of this trend in Greece, Portugal or any other country believed to be on its way out of monetary union would devastate domestic banks, saddling sovereigns with the cost of recapitalisation, which would, in turn, hasten defaults on government debt. Given that banks hold large amounts of sovereign debt, this would further weaken lenders’ balance sheets and, ultimately, lead to the effective bankruptcy of a country’s financial system. Once a country was outside of the euro zone, domestic loans and deposits would be redenominated in a new, weaker currency. Restrictions on withdrawals would be likely. Banks would probably default on most, if not all, external debt that remained denominated in euros, dollars or other hard currencies. They would be shunned by international capital markets, and reliant on funding from official sources. Larger banks might be able to find some support from income generated at subsidiaries abroad, although overseas revenue could also suffer indirectly as customers abroad shunned the beleaguered institutions. (Foreign units could also be sold to raise funds to cover losses at home.) A country’s pariah status in global markets, and the likely imposition of capital controls, would mean that banks’ fortunes would be tied almost entirely to activity in the domestic economy, which would take years to recover. 13. Could private debt in euros be enforced? This would depend on whether contracts were under the law of the countries leaving the euro zone, countries remaining in the euro zone or third countries. In the first case, the countries concerned would be likely to legislate to convert all euro contracts into national-currency contracts at the rate at which the new currency was introduced (despite likely subsequent depreciation). Contracts in other countries would legally be valid in those countries, but attempts to enforce such contracts could in many cases lead to companies declaring bankruptcy, although some multinational companies could probably survive. 14. What would happen to sovereign debt? It is likely that foreign sovereign debt would be renounced, or renegotiated under threat of being renounced. Domestic sovereign debt would be honoured, but only at the official exchange rate with the new currency.
  • 45. 45 15. Could EU internal market rules be maintained? Only partly. A key element of the EU internal market is free movement of capital, and this would almost certainly be abandoned for some years owing to the introduction of capital controls to prevent all the new money being exchanged for foreign currency. It is also quite possible that other member states would restrict free movement of labour, to avoid a huge exodus of workers to other countries in the EU. The abrogation of these rules would provide a dangerous precedent. However, the interests both of countries that had left the euro zone and of the rest would be served by maintaining rules to enable a reduced level of trade in goods and services to continue. 16. Would countries that exited the euro remain in the EU? We think so. If the assumption is that efforts would be made to maintain an internal market for the movement of goods and services, remaining in the EU would be the best way of enabling this to happen. Although it is possible to exist outside the EU and enjoy some of the benefits of membership— as in the non-EU states of Norway, Iceland and Switzerland, which are effectively integrated into most aspects of the EU internal market—it is still difficult to see why countries leaving the euro zone would leave the EU. Remaining in the EU would make it easier for internal market rules other than those on free movement of capital and labour to be observed. 17. What levels of social and political upheaval would be expected? Violent protests took place when deposits were frozen during the Argentinian crisis of 2001, and similar turbulence could occur in countries leaving the euro. Depositors would only be able to withdraw money eventually and in a new, depreciated currency. Falls in real incomes and possible shortages of imported goods would cause huge stresses. These could worsen, leading to further social and economic breakdown in subsequent years. However, it might also be possible to rebuild trust gradually as people worked together to overcome problems and the new currency stabilised. Considerable social tensions could also be seen in countries that remained in the euro. In France, for example, further severe austerity would be needed to match German demands and reassure markets. 18. What should businesses do now?
  • 46. 46 Businesses need to make contingency plans and review risk-management processes in much the same way that they would consider the impact of other major events, whether it be a natural disaster, political upheaval or the loss of a major customer. Contingency plans would depend on the nature of the company’s business and its direct exposure to the euro zone, but in general terms the main issues to consider could include finance and cash management, business continuity, revenue assumptions and targets, and client and supply chains. Below is a list of more specific actions that might be necessary:  Adjust Internal budget assumptions and targets to take account of much weaker economic conditions both in the euro zone and globally.  Examine Supply chains (going back several levels, to suppliers’ suppliers) and identify weak links. Which suppliers might go out of business?  Prepare for supply-chain disruptions, for example by increasing precautionary inventories of business-critical components sourced from euro zone countries, in case supply is interrupted.  Establish or expand alternative supplier arrangements in non-euro countries.
   Examine client relationships to determine which clients might experience financial difficulties that would prevent them from making payments or renewing contracts.  As with supply chains, consider diversifying revenue risk by expanding client bases in non-euro countries.  Limit the time cash balances are held in banks in at-risk countries.
 invoicing and billing systems, in case these need to be reconfigured to reflect changes incurrency regimes. Are internal systems robust and flexible enough to cope?  Prepare for potential disruptions to agents conducting business on the company’s behalf in at-risk countries, and to mission-critical partners such as payroll services providers. Consider contingencies such as sourcing alternative agents and partners.  Evaluate financial-management policy. Consider the impact of (a) extreme movements in exchange rates, (b) extreme movements in asset prices or (c) the sudden loss of access to credit. Are counterparties financially secure?  Ensure bank relationships are the right ones. If possible, assess whether
  • 47. 47 the banks on which the company relies are healthy enough to withstand the collapse of the euro.  Firm up funding arrangements in advance, putting in place guaranteed lines of credit if possible. Assess internal reserves of cash.  Re-examine contracts written in euros or with entities exposed to the euro crisis. Determine the extent of possible losses should contracts not be honoured, along with threats to the company’s own ability to honour contracts.  Look to lower costs and maximise operational efficiencies. Use crisis preparation to help drive organisational change, replacing obsolete or underperforming product lines.  Make contingency plans for the possibility of political or social unrest in euro countries, and evaluate the security of physical assets and staff. Thank You