SlideShare a Scribd company logo
1 of 16
Download to read offline
 
	
  
	
  
	
  
	
  
	
  
	
  
The	
  Euro	
  Crisis:	
  	
  
Structural	
  Defects	
  and	
  Ineffective	
  Policy	
  
	
  
	
  
	
  
By:	
  Alec	
  Mitchell	
  
Econ	
  442,	
  Professor	
  Menzie	
  Chinn	
  
5/11/2015	
  
Mitchell	
   1	
  
Introduction	
   	
  
While	
  the	
  collapse	
  of	
  Lehman	
  Brothers	
  in	
  September	
  of	
  2008	
  was	
  the	
  actual	
  
explosion	
  in	
  the	
  coal	
  mine	
  for	
  the	
  United	
  States,	
  the	
  Eurozone	
  failed	
  to	
  view	
  it	
  as	
  they	
  
should	
  have:	
  a	
  canary	
  for	
  the	
  longstanding	
  gas	
  leak	
  that	
  is	
  the	
  imperfect	
  Euro	
  currency	
  
union.	
  Just	
  over	
  a	
  year	
  later,	
  Ireland	
  and	
  Greece	
  saw	
  their	
  interest	
  rates	
  quickly	
  and	
  
suddenly	
  rise	
  past	
  their	
  Euro	
  counterparts	
  for	
  the	
  first	
  time	
  since	
  entering	
  the	
  union1	
  
(Table	
  1).	
  The	
  cause	
  of	
  the	
  rise	
  was	
  mixed	
  across	
  the	
  board,	
  reflecting	
  the	
  diverse	
  nature	
  of	
  
the	
  Eurozone.	
  In	
  Ireland,	
  the	
  housing	
  bubble	
  crash	
  looked	
  eerily	
  similar	
  to	
  the	
  United	
  
States,	
  but	
  was	
  magnified	
  by	
  the	
  fact	
  that	
  Irish	
  banks	
  were	
  larger	
  in	
  proportion	
  to	
  Irish	
  
GDP,	
  making	
  bailouts	
  more	
  costly	
  for	
  the	
  small	
  nation.	
  For	
  Greece,	
  longstanding	
  high	
  
deficits	
  and	
  revelations	
  as	
  to	
  their	
  actual	
  levels	
  of	
  debt	
  led	
  to	
  uncertainty	
  in	
  the	
  markets.	
  
Along	
  with	
  the	
  rest	
  of	
  the	
  Eurozone,	
  both	
  were	
  hit	
  by	
  a	
  decrease	
  in	
  US	
  imports	
  from	
  Europe	
  
and	
  a	
  devaluation	
  of	
  the	
  dollar	
  relative	
  to	
  the	
  Euro	
  heading	
  into	
  2010	
  (Table	
  2).	
  
The	
  Eurozone’s	
  Problem	
  
	
   In	
  an	
  ideal	
  currency	
  union,	
  there	
  is	
  high	
  labor	
  and	
  capital	
  mobility,	
  risk	
  smoothing,	
  
and	
  symmetric	
  business	
  cycles	
  among	
  regions.	
  For	
  the	
  Eurozone,	
  however,	
  only	
  one	
  of	
  
these	
  seems	
  to	
  be	
  true	
  in	
  capital	
  mobility.	
  While	
  the	
  zone	
  rode	
  out	
  the	
  beginning	
  of	
  the	
  US	
  
crisis,	
  cracks	
  began	
  to	
  show	
  within	
  a	
  year.	
  Austerity	
  policies	
  put	
  in	
  place	
  to	
  solve	
  high	
  debts	
  
have	
  failed	
  to	
  stem	
  the	
  crisis,	
  and	
  a	
  lack	
  of	
  unified	
  monetary	
  policy	
  has	
  crippled	
  struggling	
  
countries.	
  The	
  problem	
  now	
  facing	
  the	
  Eurozone	
  is	
  one	
  of	
  existential	
  proportions:	
  can	
  it	
  
become	
  a	
  more	
  optimal	
  currency	
  zone?	
  If	
  not,	
  should	
  it,	
  and	
  can	
  it,	
  survive?	
  
	
  
	
  
Mitchell	
   2	
  
Optimality	
  of	
  the	
  Zone	
  
	
   The	
  Eurozone’s	
  performance	
  on	
  the	
  first	
  condition	
  of	
  optimality,	
  labor	
  mobility,	
  
pales	
  in	
  comparison	
  to	
  the	
  United	
  States.	
  Blanchard	
  and	
  Katz’s	
  prescient	
  1992	
  paper	
  
described	
  the	
  difficulty	
  that	
  the	
  Eurozone	
  would	
  have	
  in	
  terms	
  of	
  labor	
  mobility;	
  they	
  
showed	
  that	
  individual	
  US	
  states	
  tend	
  to	
  recover	
  from	
  asymmetric	
  shocks	
  through	
  
moderate	
  to	
  high	
  labor	
  mobility.2	
  In	
  fact,	
  a	
  2014	
  European	
  Commission	
  report	
  estimated	
  
that	
  cross-­‐country	
  mobility	
  in	
  the	
  EU	
  was	
  .2	
  percent,	
  less	
  than	
  one-­‐tenth	
  of	
  the	
  2.7	
  percent	
  
state-­‐to-­‐state	
  mobility	
  in	
  the	
  US.3	
  This	
  does	
  not	
  bode	
  well	
  for	
  the	
  Eurozone	
  considering	
  that	
  
the	
  pressures	
  faced	
  by	
  individual	
  depressed	
  countries	
  are	
  due,	
  in	
  large	
  part,	
  to	
  external	
  
demand	
  imbalances.	
  A	
  2015	
  working	
  paper	
  by	
  Emmanuel	
  Farhi	
  and	
  Ivan	
  Werning	
  shows	
  
that	
  mobility	
  out	
  of	
  depressed	
  regions	
  has	
  a	
  significantly	
  positive	
  effect	
  on	
  those	
  who	
  
decide	
  to	
  stay,	
  but	
  only	
  when	
  the	
  source	
  of	
  demand	
  imbalances	
  is	
  external	
  (such	
  as	
  the	
  
current	
  Euro	
  Crisis).4	
  In	
  sum,	
  the	
  unique	
  structure	
  of	
  the	
  Eurozone	
  puts	
  it	
  at	
  a	
  disadvantage	
  
for	
  the	
  first	
  pillar	
  of	
  optimality,	
  a	
  condition	
  that	
  may	
  need	
  to	
  change	
  if	
  it	
  is	
  to	
  survive.	
  
	
   The	
  strongest	
  area	
  for	
  the	
  Eurozone	
  is	
  capital	
  mobility,	
  with	
  both	
  historical	
  and	
  
current	
  trade	
  agreements	
  providing	
  a	
  strong	
  base.	
  The	
  1957	
  Treaty	
  of	
  Rome,	
  a	
  precursor	
  to	
  
the	
  eventual	
  Treaty	
  of	
  Maastricht,	
  created	
  the	
  European	
  Economic	
  Community,	
  which	
  
provided	
  for	
  common	
  goods	
  markets	
  and	
  customs	
  rates.	
  The	
  treaty	
  was	
  a	
  foundation	
  on	
  
which	
  the	
  future	
  Eurozone	
  established	
  strong	
  capital	
  mobility.	
  Authority	
  over	
  the	
  customs	
  
union	
  was	
  transferred	
  to	
  the	
  European	
  Union	
  after	
  its	
  inception,	
  and	
  was	
  expanded	
  to	
  
include	
  all	
  member	
  states.	
  Additionally,	
  the	
  introduction	
  of	
  a	
  single	
  currency	
  has	
  made	
  
transfer	
  of	
  capital	
  easier,	
  to	
  the	
  tune	
  of	
  an	
  approximate	
  10	
  percent	
  increase.5	
  
Mitchell	
   3	
  
	
   Perhaps	
  the	
  Eurozone’s	
  trickiest	
  yet	
  most	
  necessary	
  problem	
  to	
  change,	
  risk	
  
smoothing	
  across	
  countries	
  is	
  notably	
  absent	
  in	
  the	
  Eurozone.	
  Ironically,	
  the	
  Eurozone	
  
resembles	
  the	
  short-­‐lived	
  Articles	
  of	
  Confederation	
  in	
  the	
  United	
  States,	
  with	
  the	
  central	
  
authority	
  unable	
  to	
  implement	
  many	
  fiscal	
  or	
  monetary	
  policies	
  without	
  support	
  from	
  
member	
  states.	
  Unlike	
  the	
  current	
  United	
  States	
  system,	
  whereby	
  the	
  federal	
  government	
  
can	
  shift	
  tax	
  burdens	
  and	
  benefits	
  to	
  states	
  hit	
  by	
  asymmetric	
  shocks,	
  the	
  Eurozone	
  is	
  not	
  
set	
  up	
  to	
  complete	
  such	
  actions.	
  The	
  supremacy	
  of	
  individual	
  members	
  over	
  the	
  European	
  
Parliament	
  and	
  Central	
  Bank	
  puts	
  a	
  major	
  damper	
  on	
  the	
  ability	
  to	
  shift	
  benefits	
  around	
  
the	
  Union.	
  Individual	
  member	
  states	
  would	
  need	
  to	
  use	
  their	
  own	
  tax	
  receipts	
  to	
  support	
  
failing	
  countries,	
  something	
  politically	
  difficult	
  for	
  national	
  legislatures.	
  Indeed,	
  the	
  
European	
  Fiscal	
  Compact	
  forces	
  members	
  to	
  keep	
  their	
  deficits	
  under	
  3	
  percent	
  or	
  face	
  
fines,	
  and	
  Germany	
  has	
  so	
  far	
  stood	
  strong	
  in	
  refusing	
  the	
  most	
  recent	
  bailout	
  offers	
  from	
  
Greece.6	
  On	
  the	
  monetary	
  policy	
  front,	
  quantitative	
  easing	
  has	
  long	
  been	
  off	
  the	
  table	
  due	
  to	
  
both	
  structural	
  EU	
  requirements	
  and	
  German	
  opposition.7	
  Simply	
  put,	
  current	
  fiscal	
  and	
  
monetary	
  policies	
  do	
  not	
  align	
  with	
  necessary	
  structures	
  required	
  for	
  an	
  optimal	
  currency	
  
union.	
  
	
   The	
  last	
  problem	
  facing	
  the	
  Eurozone	
  is	
  the	
  asymmetric	
  business	
  cycles	
  facing	
  
member	
  states.	
  A	
  2008	
  research	
  paper	
  estimated	
  that	
  there	
  were	
  two	
  groups	
  of	
  countries:	
  
a	
  core	
  and	
  a	
  periphery.	
  The	
  core	
  consisted	
  of	
  Germany,	
  France,	
  The	
  Netherlands,	
  and	
  
Finland	
  (among	
  others),	
  while	
  the	
  periphery	
  was	
  rounded	
  out	
  by	
  Greece,	
  Ireland,	
  Portugal,	
  
and	
  Spain.1	
  In	
  addition	
  to	
  finding	
  that	
  both	
  groups	
  are	
  indeed	
  out	
  of	
  cycle,	
  the	
  researchers	
  
also	
  found	
  that	
  the	
  Euro	
  has	
  done	
  little	
  to	
  bring	
  them	
  into	
  alignment.8	
  As	
  such,	
  it	
  is	
  difficult	
  
	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  
1	
  The	
  last	
  GIIPS	
  country,	
  Italy,	
  was	
  the	
  only	
  one	
  included	
  within	
  the	
  core	
  group	
  
Mitchell	
   4	
  
for	
  a	
  central	
  bank	
  to	
  utilize	
  many	
  available	
  monetary	
  policies	
  in	
  a	
  way	
  that	
  can	
  help	
  buoy	
  
the	
  struggling	
  periphery	
  countries,	
  while	
  not	
  also	
  harming	
  the	
  stable	
  core	
  countries.	
  
How	
  the	
  Crisis	
  Has	
  Played	
  Out	
  
Eurozone	
  Policy	
  
	
   The	
  Treaty	
  of	
  Lisbon	
  and	
  previous	
  pacts	
  in	
  the	
  EU	
  impose	
  significant	
  restrictions	
  on	
  
Euro-­‐wide	
  policy	
  and	
  place	
  heavy	
  burdens	
  on	
  member	
  states	
  to	
  keep	
  their	
  financial	
  
conditions	
  within	
  certain	
  bounds.	
  Article	
  123	
  imposes	
  a	
  prohibition	
  on	
  the	
  “direct”	
  
purchase	
  by	
  the	
  ECB	
  of	
  “(Union	
  Institution)	
  debt	
  instruments,”	
  and	
  many	
  have	
  interpreted	
  
this	
  to	
  preclude	
  any	
  monetary	
  financing	
  whatsoever.	
  9	
  Article	
  124	
  prohibits	
  privileged	
  
access	
  to	
  financial	
  institutions	
  for	
  any	
  union	
  institution.10	
  In	
  addition,	
  article	
  125	
  imposes	
  
severe	
  restrictions	
  on	
  the	
  ability	
  of	
  the	
  EU	
  to	
  “bail	
  out”	
  any	
  government	
  within	
  the	
  EU.11	
  
The	
  European	
  Fiscal	
  Compact,	
  signed	
  in	
  2012,	
  places	
  tighter	
  controls	
  on	
  the	
  longstanding	
  
policy	
  that	
  member	
  countries	
  must	
  have	
  less	
  than	
  3	
  percent	
  deficit	
  to	
  GDP	
  and	
  60	
  percent	
  
debt	
  to	
  GDP	
  ratios.12	
  Finally,	
  all	
  monetary	
  policy	
  is	
  complicated	
  by	
  the	
  fact	
  that	
  the	
  ECB’s	
  
primary	
  job	
  is	
  limited	
  to	
  keeping	
  inflation	
  close	
  to	
  2	
  percent.13	
  
	
   These	
  policies,	
  while	
  not	
  inherently	
  meant	
  to	
  impede	
  recovery,	
  clash	
  with	
  what	
  
many	
  economists	
  consider	
  the	
  best	
  set	
  of	
  policies	
  in	
  a	
  recession.	
  The	
  most	
  confusing	
  policy	
  
stance	
  is	
  the	
  EU’s	
  resistance	
  to	
  quantitative	
  easing	
  in	
  the	
  sovereign	
  bond	
  and	
  securities	
  
markets.	
  Most	
  advanced	
  economies	
  rely	
  on	
  countercyclical	
  monetary	
  policy	
  to	
  smooth	
  the	
  
business	
  cycle,	
  encouraging	
  growth	
  in	
  troughs	
  and	
  putting	
  on	
  the	
  brakes	
  during	
  peaks.14	
  
Such	
  action	
  in	
  recessions	
  can	
  lower	
  interest	
  rates	
  by	
  driving	
  up	
  the	
  demand	
  in	
  sovereign	
  
bond	
  markets,	
  which	
  have	
  seen	
  skyrocketing	
  interest	
  rates	
  for	
  Ireland	
  and	
  Greece.	
  
However,	
  Article	
  123	
  and	
  the	
  ECB’s	
  own	
  instructions	
  effectively	
  limit	
  their	
  ability	
  to	
  enact	
  
Mitchell	
   5	
  
any	
  such	
  policy,	
  even	
  as	
  the	
  crisis	
  has	
  leapt	
  to	
  historic	
  proportions	
  across	
  the	
  globe	
  and	
  EU.	
  
Finally,	
  only	
  two	
  months	
  ago,	
  years	
  after	
  the	
  crisis	
  began,	
  the	
  ECB	
  began	
  a	
  €1.1	
  trillion	
  
secondary	
  market	
  bond-­‐buying	
  program,	
  now	
  under	
  intense	
  political	
  and	
  legal	
  
controversy.15	
  So	
  why	
  was	
  policy	
  not	
  changed?	
  In	
  short,	
  political	
  considerations	
  trumped	
  
economic	
  theory.	
  Germany,	
  the	
  economic	
  bedrock	
  of	
  the	
  Eurozone,	
  has	
  flat	
  out	
  refused	
  to	
  
accept	
  such	
  relief	
  to	
  debt	
  stricken	
  countries.	
  Both	
  of	
  their	
  ECB	
  board	
  members	
  have	
  openly	
  
opposed	
  such	
  actions,	
  and	
  Chancellor	
  Angela	
  Merkel	
  has	
  expressed	
  her	
  worry	
  that	
  such	
  
actions	
  will	
  allow	
  distressed	
  countries	
  to	
  delay	
  or	
  even	
  fail	
  to	
  enact	
  deficit-­‐cutting	
  
reforms.16	
  
	
   These	
  debt	
  reforms,	
  embedded	
  within	
  the	
  European	
  Fiscal	
  Compact,	
  go	
  against	
  a	
  
much	
  more	
  controversial	
  area	
  of	
  economic	
  theory.	
  In	
  order	
  for	
  countries	
  such	
  as	
  Ireland	
  
and	
  Greece	
  to	
  hit	
  the	
  3	
  percent	
  deficit	
  and	
  60	
  percent	
  debt	
  marks,	
  higher	
  taxes	
  and/or	
  
extreme	
  austerity	
  measures	
  have	
  to	
  be	
  implemented.	
  Some	
  decision	
  makers	
  used	
  a	
  widely	
  
cited	
  research	
  paper	
  by	
  Reinhart	
  and	
  Rogoff	
  as	
  empirical	
  evidence	
  that	
  high	
  debt	
  leads	
  to	
  
slower	
  growth,	
  therefore	
  vindicating	
  the	
  Eurozone’s	
  strict	
  policies.17	
  However,	
  many	
  
economists	
  criticized	
  the	
  paper,	
  and	
  the	
  authors	
  were	
  forced	
  to	
  clarify	
  that	
  the	
  two	
  were	
  
found	
  to	
  be	
  “associated,”	
  not	
  necessary	
  cause	
  and	
  effect.18	
  Yet,	
  other	
  research	
  has	
  found	
  
that	
  debt	
  can	
  actually	
  have	
  a	
  positive	
  effect	
  on	
  GDP	
  growth,	
  up	
  to	
  certain	
  points.19	
  Even	
  
further,	
  some	
  research	
  has	
  found	
  no	
  threshold	
  at	
  which	
  GDP	
  growth	
  is	
  hampered	
  by	
  
additional	
  debt.20	
  So	
  what	
  is	
  the	
  correct	
  policy	
  choice	
  here?	
  The	
  general	
  consensus	
  in	
  the	
  
economic	
  realm	
  is	
  that	
  higher	
  deficits	
  and	
  debt	
  in	
  the	
  short	
  run	
  can	
  certainly	
  have	
  positive	
  
effects	
  on	
  growth,	
  much	
  in	
  line	
  with	
  the	
  Keynesian	
  aggregate	
  demand	
  models.	
  The	
  most	
  
uncertainty	
  occurs,	
  however,	
  on	
  whether	
  there	
  is	
  a	
  certain	
  level	
  of	
  debt	
  that	
  starts	
  to	
  
Mitchell	
   6	
  
impede	
  growth	
  in	
  the	
  long	
  run.	
  Therefore,	
  it	
  seems	
  likely	
  that	
  the	
  EU	
  policy	
  here	
  is	
  likewise	
  
counter	
  to	
  what	
  should	
  be	
  pursued	
  in	
  recessed	
  economies,	
  but	
  the	
  evidence	
  is	
  not	
  as	
  firmly	
  
grounded	
  as	
  is	
  countercyclical	
  monetary	
  policy.	
  
	
   The	
  last	
  controversial	
  Eurozone	
  recessionary	
  policy	
  is	
  the	
  prohibition	
  on	
  most	
  bail-­‐
outs.	
  Unlike	
  countercyclical	
  and	
  austerity	
  policies,	
  the	
  evidence	
  on	
  bail-­‐outs	
  is	
  decidedly	
  
mixed,	
  with	
  economists	
  landing	
  on	
  both	
  ends	
  of	
  the	
  scale.	
  On	
  one	
  hand,	
  when	
  assessing	
  the	
  
effects	
  of	
  the	
  US	
  bailout,	
  a	
  University	
  of	
  Chicago	
  forum	
  polled	
  49	
  leading	
  economists,	
  who	
  
on	
  average	
  agreed	
  that	
  its	
  benefits	
  outweighed	
  the	
  costs,	
  that	
  unemployment	
  was	
  lower	
  as	
  
a	
  result,	
  and	
  that	
  businesses	
  were	
  not	
  be	
  incentivized	
  to	
  harm	
  the	
  economy	
  further.21	
  
Additionally,	
  empirical	
  research	
  has	
  shown	
  that	
  not	
  only	
  are	
  bailouts	
  necessary	
  to	
  prevent	
  
a	
  banking	
  crisis	
  which	
  would	
  wreak	
  havoc	
  on	
  an	
  economy,	
  but	
  even	
  that	
  Chancellor	
  
Merkel’s	
  strong	
  resistance	
  to	
  such	
  policies	
  led	
  to	
  higher	
  bailout	
  costs	
  for	
  distressed	
  
countries.22	
  On	
  the	
  other	
  hand,	
  research	
  of	
  the	
  US	
  bailout	
  has	
  found	
  that	
  banks	
  did	
  end	
  up	
  
having	
  riskier	
  portfolios	
  after	
  they	
  were	
  bailed	
  out,	
  evidence	
  of	
  a	
  moral	
  hazard.23	
  What	
  is	
  
seen	
  overall	
  is	
  that	
  economic	
  theory	
  tends	
  to	
  agree	
  that	
  a	
  bailout	
  of	
  some	
  undercapitalized	
  
financial	
  institutions	
  is	
  necessary	
  to	
  avoid	
  further	
  economic	
  shock,	
  but	
  some	
  economists	
  
show	
  that	
  there	
  is	
  proof	
  that	
  those	
  institutions	
  continue	
  the	
  same	
  risky	
  behavior.	
  Here,	
  
Chancellor	
  Merkel’s	
  concerns	
  about	
  moral	
  hazard	
  find	
  stronger	
  ground.	
  Bailouts	
  seem	
  to	
  be	
  
beneficial	
  to	
  an	
  economy	
  when	
  they	
  include	
  strong	
  regulations	
  to	
  prevent	
  mistakes	
  from	
  
happening	
  again.	
  However,	
  Germany’s	
  insistence	
  for	
  bailouts	
  paired	
  with	
  strict	
  austerity	
  
measures	
  muddles	
  recovery.	
  
	
   So,	
  how	
  do	
  these	
  policies	
  fit	
  within	
  specific	
  Eurozone	
  countries?	
  Below,	
  the	
  
examples	
  of	
  Ireland	
  and	
  Greece	
  are	
  considered.	
  Irish	
  banks,	
  second	
  largest	
  in	
  the	
  world	
  in	
  
Mitchell	
   7	
  
terms	
  of	
  GDP,	
  were	
  hit	
  hard	
  by	
  the	
  housing	
  bubble	
  and	
  their	
  economy	
  was	
  the	
  first	
  to	
  
tumble.	
  Ireland	
  accepted	
  a	
  contentious	
  bailout	
  with	
  the	
  strict	
  austerity	
  that	
  Germany	
  
wanted,	
  and	
  their	
  economy	
  has	
  recovered	
  in	
  part.	
  Greece,	
  bogged	
  down	
  by	
  a	
  drop	
  in	
  
exports,	
  bank	
  bailouts,	
  and	
  high	
  interest	
  rates,	
  was	
  forced	
  to	
  implement	
  deep	
  austerity	
  in	
  
accordance	
  with	
  bailout	
  partners.	
  Their	
  economy,	
  however,	
  has	
  turned	
  to	
  shambles.	
  
Impact	
  on	
  Ireland	
  
	
   Ireland	
  was	
  hit	
  hardest	
  by	
  the	
  mortgage	
  and	
  financial	
  crisis.	
  Irish	
  banks,	
  with	
  
increased	
  availability	
  of	
  capital	
  from	
  short	
  term	
  lending,	
  increased	
  their	
  balance	
  sheets	
  by	
  
enormous	
  amounts.	
  In	
  2008,	
  Irish	
  banks	
  held	
  assets	
  worth	
  783	
  percent	
  of	
  GDP,	
  second	
  to	
  
only	
  Luxembourg.24	
  The	
  vast	
  majority	
  of	
  these	
  assets	
  were	
  held	
  in	
  property,	
  while	
  at	
  the	
  
same	
  time,	
  the	
  Irish	
  government	
  increased	
  spending	
  and	
  relied	
  more	
  heavily	
  on	
  property	
  
taxes	
  to	
  make	
  up	
  government	
  revenue.	
  As	
  a	
  result,	
  in	
  2006	
  property	
  taxes	
  reached	
  of	
  peak	
  
of	
  almost	
  20	
  percent	
  of	
  total	
  Irish	
  tax	
  revenue.25	
  This	
  reliance	
  on	
  property	
  by	
  both	
  the	
  Irish	
  
financial	
  institutions	
  and	
  government	
  led	
  to	
  a	
  perfect	
  storm	
  as	
  the	
  housing	
  bubble	
  burst.	
  	
  
	
   When	
  the	
  US	
  crisis	
  hit,	
  housing	
  prices	
  fell	
  and	
  borrowers	
  defaulted	
  on	
  payments.	
  
The	
  short	
  term	
  borrowing	
  that	
  Irish	
  banks	
  had	
  so	
  heavily	
  relied	
  on	
  to	
  increase	
  their	
  
balance	
  sheets	
  began	
  to	
  dry	
  up,	
  limiting	
  options	
  for	
  liquidity	
  as	
  the	
  banks	
  began	
  to	
  feel	
  the	
  
squeeze.	
  As	
  banks	
  used	
  up	
  their	
  available	
  capital,	
  the	
  Irish	
  government	
  stepped	
  in	
  and	
  
guaranteed	
  to	
  cover	
  the	
  liabilities	
  of	
  the	
  struggling	
  institutions.	
  However,	
  in	
  conjunction	
  
with	
  sudden	
  structural	
  deficits	
  due	
  to	
  a	
  plunge	
  in	
  property	
  tax	
  revenue,	
  Irish	
  debt	
  soared	
  
from	
  25	
  percent	
  of	
  GDP	
  in	
  2008	
  to	
  over	
  111	
  percent	
  by	
  2012.26	
  At	
  the	
  same	
  time,	
  Irish	
  
yields	
  increased	
  from	
  4	
  percent	
  in	
  2008	
  to	
  almost	
  12	
  percent	
  by	
  the	
  middle	
  of	
  2011,	
  
making	
  additional	
  borrowing	
  too	
  costly.27	
  
Mitchell	
   8	
  
	
   The	
  one-­‐dimensional	
  scope	
  of	
  the	
  Irish	
  crisis	
  and	
  the	
  nature	
  of	
  their	
  exports	
  made	
  
the	
  path	
  to	
  growth	
  difficult,	
  yet	
  simpler	
  than	
  Greece.	
  In	
  response	
  to	
  the	
  banking	
  and	
  
emerging	
  government	
  debt	
  crisis,	
  Ireland	
  was	
  essentially	
  forced	
  into	
  a	
  European	
  
Union/International	
  Monetary	
  Fund	
  bailout	
  by	
  the	
  ECB.28	
  The	
  recovery	
  has	
  since	
  been	
  slow	
  
and	
  inconsistent.	
  Ireland’s	
  GDP	
  grew	
  3.2	
  percent	
  in	
  Q4	
  2012,	
  then	
  dropped	
  3.7	
  percent	
  the	
  
next	
  quarter.	
  It	
  had	
  2	
  percent+	
  growth	
  in	
  Q3	
  2013	
  and	
  Q1	
  2014,	
  then	
  leveled	
  off	
  to	
  0.5	
  
percent	
  in	
  the	
  last	
  two	
  quarters	
  of	
  2014.29	
  Unemployment	
  remains	
  at	
  10	
  percent,	
  wages	
  are	
  
below	
  2007	
  levels,	
  and	
  consumer	
  spending	
  growth	
  lags	
  at	
  0.3	
  percent,	
  in	
  part	
  due	
  to	
  higher	
  
taxes	
  implemented	
  to	
  comply	
  with	
  austerity	
  requirements.30,31,32	
  So,	
  while	
  the	
  bailout	
  
certainly	
  aided	
  the	
  Irish	
  economy,	
  the	
  austerity	
  measures	
  possibly	
  hampered	
  recovery,	
  
with	
  continued	
  low	
  consumer	
  spending,	
  low	
  growth	
  in	
  wages,	
  and	
  high	
  unemployment.	
  
Impact	
  on	
  Greece	
  
	
   Unlike	
  Ireland,	
  which	
  was	
  impacted	
  mostly	
  by	
  the	
  banking	
  crash	
  and	
  housing	
  
bubble,	
  Greece	
  was	
  hit	
  hardest	
  by	
  a	
  dramatic	
  drop	
  in	
  exports,	
  high	
  government	
  debt,	
  and	
  a	
  
bookkeeping	
  scandal	
  that	
  scarred	
  the	
  government’s	
  credibility.	
  Greece’s	
  exports	
  are	
  mainly	
  
low	
  value	
  raw	
  materials,	
  while	
  among	
  Greece’s	
  largest	
  trading	
  partners	
  are	
  Italy,	
  Turkey,	
  
and	
  Cyprus,	
  all	
  hit	
  hardest	
  by	
  the	
  global	
  recession.33	
  Greece’s	
  exports	
  plummeted	
  21%	
  from	
  
2008	
  to	
  2009,	
  only	
  recovering	
  to	
  their	
  2008	
  level	
  in	
  2014	
  (Table	
  3).34	
  Greece	
  also	
  faced	
  a	
  
skyrocketing	
  level	
  of	
  government	
  debt:	
  from	
  2005-­‐2010,	
  their	
  debt	
  rose	
  from	
  100	
  percent	
  
to	
  148	
  percent	
  of	
  GDP.35	
  With	
  a	
  disappearance	
  of	
  risk	
  and	
  interest	
  rates	
  tied	
  to	
  the	
  Euro	
  
average,	
  Greece	
  was	
  able	
  to	
  borrow	
  large	
  amounts	
  of	
  money	
  at	
  what	
  turned	
  out	
  to	
  be	
  
insanely	
  cheap	
  prices.	
  That	
  changed	
  when,	
  in	
  early	
  January,	
  2010,	
  the	
  European	
  
Commission	
  released	
  a	
  shocking	
  report	
  that	
  accused	
  Greece	
  of	
  falsifying	
  records	
  to	
  cover	
  
Mitchell	
   9	
  
up	
  true	
  debt	
  levels.36	
  Within	
  one	
  year,	
  Greece’s	
  bond	
  yields	
  rose	
  from	
  6	
  percent	
  to	
  9.5	
  
percent,	
  and	
  peaked	
  at	
  29.2	
  percent	
  in	
  early	
  2012	
  (Table	
  1).	
  
	
   With	
  skyrocketing	
  bond	
  yields,	
  Greece	
  was	
  hit	
  by	
  both	
  a	
  drop	
  in	
  tax	
  receipts	
  
combined	
  with	
  the	
  inability	
  to	
  borrow	
  at	
  reasonable	
  prices.	
  Greece	
  was	
  given	
  two	
  bailouts	
  
as	
  a	
  result	
  of	
  their	
  rising	
  debt	
  and	
  growth	
  crisis,	
  one	
  in	
  May	
  2010	
  and	
  another	
  in	
  July	
  2011.	
  
Both	
  programs,	
  jointly	
  administered	
  by	
  the	
  EU,	
  ECB,	
  and	
  IMF2,	
  required	
  deep	
  austerity	
  cuts.	
  
The	
  Greek	
  government	
  did	
  indeed	
  reduce	
  government	
  spending,	
  with	
  seven	
  successive	
  
austerity	
  plans	
  from	
  2010-­‐2013,	
  cutting	
  public	
  workers’	
  pay,	
  overtime,	
  and	
  jobs,	
  while	
  
raising	
  and	
  enforcing	
  existing	
  taxes	
  to	
  increase	
  receipts.	
  However,	
  unlike	
  Ireland’s	
  
moderate	
  recovery,	
  Greece	
  plunged.	
  GDP	
  fell	
  every	
  quarter	
  from	
  2010-­‐2014,	
  110,000	
  
businesses	
  declared	
  bankruptcy,	
  and	
  unemployment	
  rose	
  from	
  10	
  percent	
  to	
  27	
  
percent.37,38	
  The	
  drop	
  in	
  public	
  sector	
  and	
  private	
  sector	
  employment	
  led	
  to	
  lower	
  tax	
  
receipts,	
  and	
  massive	
  protests	
  led	
  to	
  even	
  lower	
  productivity	
  and	
  political	
  chaos.	
  With	
  an	
  
inability	
  to	
  borrow	
  on	
  the	
  bond	
  market	
  and	
  pressures	
  from	
  the	
  bailout	
  troika,	
  Greece	
  
continued	
  to	
  cut,	
  and	
  their	
  economy	
  continued	
  to	
  fall.	
  Only	
  recently,	
  in	
  January	
  2015,	
  did	
  
Greece’s	
  anti-­‐austerity	
  party	
  SYRIZA	
  sweep	
  into	
  power,	
  promising	
  to	
  undo	
  the	
  austerity	
  
measures	
  implemented	
  over	
  the	
  past	
  five	
  years.	
  
	
   The	
  Eurozone’s	
  policies	
  had	
  an	
  even	
  greater	
  effect	
  on	
  Greece	
  than	
  Ireland,	
  and	
  
played	
  a	
  large	
  part	
  in	
  their	
  deep	
  recession.	
  First,	
  the	
  prohibition	
  on	
  countercyclical	
  
monetary	
  policy	
  prevented	
  Greece	
  from	
  spending	
  money	
  on	
  a	
  stimulus	
  package	
  like	
  the	
  
United	
  States.	
  Second,	
  the	
  ECB’s	
  decision	
  not	
  to	
  devalue	
  the	
  Euro	
  meant	
  that	
  the	
  drop	
  in	
  
Greek	
  exports	
  had	
  no	
  cushion.	
  Third,	
  the	
  bailouts	
  and	
  their	
  strict	
  austerity	
  provisions	
  
	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  
2	
  The	
  troika	
  partnership	
  was	
  formed	
  for	
  Ireland	
  and	
  Greece	
  in	
  part	
  because	
  of	
  the	
  severe	
  
restrictions	
  placed	
  on	
  bailouts	
  by	
  Article	
  125	
  
Mitchell	
   10	
  
forced	
  Greece	
  to	
  cut	
  spending	
  by	
  massive	
  amounts,	
  in	
  the	
  hopes	
  that	
  international	
  
investors	
  would	
  lower	
  bond	
  yields.	
  Quite	
  simply,	
  it	
  did	
  not	
  work.	
  The	
  drop	
  in	
  aggregate	
  
demand	
  from	
  lower	
  government	
  spending	
  led	
  to	
  a	
  falling	
  GDP	
  and	
  higher	
  unemployment,	
  
as	
  the	
  classical	
  Keynesian	
  model	
  predicts.	
  Greece	
  also	
  did	
  not	
  see	
  lower	
  sovereign	
  bond	
  
interest	
  rates	
  until	
  mid-­‐2013,	
  so	
  borrowing	
  was	
  out	
  of	
  the	
  question.	
  While	
  SYRIZA’s	
  
success	
  has	
  caused	
  a	
  rise	
  in	
  interest	
  rates	
  past	
  10	
  percent,	
  the	
  ECB’s	
  decision	
  to	
  finally	
  
implement	
  a	
  quantitative	
  easing	
  program	
  should	
  help	
  dull	
  the	
  effects.	
  However,	
  many	
  
economists	
  worry	
  that	
  the	
  plan	
  is	
  “too	
  little	
  too	
  late”,	
  and	
  that	
  the	
  Greek	
  economy	
  is	
  stuck	
  
with	
  slow	
  growth	
  for	
  years	
  to	
  come.39	
  
Conclusion	
  
	
   The	
  Eurozone	
  crisis’s	
  origins	
  can	
  be	
  blamed	
  partially	
  on	
  the	
  United	
  States,	
  but	
  the	
  
slow	
  recovery	
  of	
  countries	
  like	
  Ireland	
  and	
  Greece	
  is	
  entirely	
  due	
  to	
  the	
  zone’s	
  optimality,	
  
poor	
  government	
  management,	
  and	
  ineffective	
  EU	
  policies.	
  The	
  Euro	
  currency	
  union	
  has	
  
low	
  labor	
  mobility,	
  poor	
  fiscal	
  policy,	
  and	
  asymmetric	
  business	
  cycles.	
  These	
  three	
  failures	
  
have	
  led	
  to	
  the	
  current	
  crisis,	
  wherein	
  the	
  Eurozone	
  has	
  faced	
  its	
  biggest	
  test	
  yet.	
  At	
  the	
  
same	
  time,	
  some	
  union	
  members	
  allowed	
  their	
  economic	
  situations	
  to	
  become	
  unstable.	
  	
  
Ireland’s	
  banks	
  ballooned	
  past	
  reasonable	
  sizes	
  and	
  Greece’s	
  debt	
  passed	
  100	
  percent	
  of	
  
GDP.	
  When	
  the	
  crash	
  hit,	
  ECB	
  policies	
  with	
  regards	
  to	
  quantitative	
  easing,	
  deficit	
  reduction,	
  
and	
  bailouts	
  slowed	
  their	
  recovery.	
  While	
  Ireland	
  has	
  gained	
  back	
  some	
  of	
  the	
  economic	
  
indicators	
  it	
  lost	
  during	
  its	
  crisis,	
  severe	
  structural	
  problems	
  remain.	
  In	
  Greece,	
  the	
  policies	
  
have	
  led	
  to	
  an	
  outright	
  depression.	
  Even	
  though	
  the	
  ECB’s	
  monetary	
  policy	
  may	
  finally	
  be	
  
catching	
  up,	
  the	
  road	
  to	
  recovery	
  looks	
  long	
  and	
  tenuous.	
  	
  
Mitchell	
   11	
  
	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  
1	
  European	
  Central	
  Bank,	
  and	
  European	
  Commission.	
  Long-­‐term	
  interest	
  rate	
  statistics	
  for	
  EU	
  
Member	
  States.	
  14	
  Apr.	
  2015.	
  Raw	
  data.	
  
Https://www.ecb.europa.eu/stats/money/long/html/index.en.html,	
  Frankfurt.	
  
2	
  Blanchard,	
  Olivier	
  Jean,	
  Lawrence	
  F.	
  Katz,	
  Robert	
  E.	
  Hall,	
  and	
  Barry	
  Eichengreen.	
  "Regional	
  
Evolutions."	
  Brookings	
  Papers	
  on	
  Economic	
  Activity	
  1992.1	
  (1992):	
  n.	
  pag.	
  Harvard	
  Scholar.	
  
Web.	
  4	
  May	
  2015.	
  
3	
  European	
  Union.	
  European	
  Commission.	
  Directorate-­‐General	
  for	
  Economic	
  and	
  Financial	
  
Affairs.	
  Labour	
  Mobility	
  and	
  Labour	
  Market	
  Adjustment	
  in	
  the	
  EU.	
  By	
  Alfonso	
  Arpaia,	
  Aron	
  Kiss,	
  
Cees	
  Diks,	
  Balazs	
  Palvolgyi,	
  and	
  Alessandro	
  Turrini.	
  Luxembourg:	
  Publications	
  Office,	
  2015.	
  
Europa.eu.	
  European	
  Commission,	
  Dec.	
  2014.	
  Web.	
  3	
  May	
  2015.	
  
4	
  Farhi,	
  Emmanuel,	
  and	
  Iván	
  Werning.	
  "Labor	
  Mobility	
  Within	
  Currency	
  Unions."	
  National	
  
Bureau	
  of	
  Economic	
  Research	
  (2014):	
  n.	
  pag.	
  NBER.	
  Web.	
  7	
  May	
  2015.	
  
<http://www.nber.org/papers/w20105>.	
  
5	
  Baldwin,	
  Richard.	
  "The	
  Euro's	
  Trade	
  Effects."	
  European	
  Central	
  Bank	
  Working	
  Papers	
  Series	
  
594	
  (2006):	
  n.	
  pag.	
  Europa.eu.	
  Web.	
  7	
  May	
  2015.	
  
6	
  Monaghan,	
  Angela.	
  "Germany	
  Rejects	
  Greek	
  Bailout	
  Plan	
  -­‐	
  As	
  It	
  Happened."	
  The	
  Guardian.	
  The	
  
Guardian,	
  19	
  Feb.	
  2015.	
  Web.	
  3	
  May	
  2015.	
  
7	
  European	
  Central	
  Bank.	
  "Fiscal	
  Policies."	
  Europa.eu.	
  European	
  Central	
  Bank,	
  n.d.	
  Web.	
  4	
  May	
  
2015.	
  
8	
  Giannone,	
  Domenico,	
  Michele	
  Lenza,	
  and	
  Lucrezia	
  Reichlin.	
  "Business	
  Cycles	
  in	
  the	
  Euro	
  
Area."	
  National	
  Bureau	
  of	
  Economic	
  Research	
  (2008):	
  n.	
  pag.	
  NBER.	
  Web.	
  4	
  May	
  2015.	
  
<http://www.nber.org/papers/w14529>.	
  
9	
  Eurostep,	
  and	
  EEPA.	
  "Article	
  123."	
  The	
  Lisbon	
  Treaty.	
  Eurostep	
  -­‐	
  EEPA,	
  2008.	
  Web.	
  5	
  May	
  
2015.	
  
10	
  Eurostep,	
  and	
  EEPA.	
  "Article	
  124."	
  The	
  Lisbon	
  Treaty.	
  Eurostep	
  -­‐	
  EEPA,	
  2008.	
  Web.	
  5	
  May	
  
2015.	
  
11	
  Eurostep,	
  and	
  EEPA.	
  "Article	
  125."	
  The	
  Lisbon	
  Treaty.	
  Eurostep	
  -­‐	
  EEPA,	
  2008.	
  Web.	
  5	
  May	
  
2015.	
  
12	
  European	
  Central	
  Bank.	
  "A	
  Fiscal	
  Compact	
  For	
  A	
  Stronger	
  Economic	
  and	
  Monetary	
  Union."	
  
ECB	
  Articles	
  (2012):	
  79-­‐94.	
  Europa.eu.	
  ECB,	
  May	
  2012.	
  Web.	
  5	
  May	
  2015.	
  
13	
  European	
  Central	
  Bank.	
  "Monetary	
  Policy."	
  Europa.eu.	
  ECB,	
  n.d.	
  Web.	
  6	
  May	
  2015.	
  
14	
  Coulibaly,	
  Brahima.	
  "The	
  Long	
  Road	
  to	
  Countercyclical	
  Monetary	
  Policy	
  in	
  Emerging	
  Market	
  
Economies."	
  FederalReserve.gov.	
  Board	
  of	
  Governors	
  of	
  the	
  Federal	
  Reserve	
  System,	
  3	
  Dec.	
  
2013.	
  Web.	
  5	
  May	
  2015.	
  
15	
  Blackstone,	
  Brian,	
  Paul	
  Hannon,	
  and	
  Marcus	
  Walker.	
  "Aggressive	
  ECB	
  Stimulus	
  Ushers	
  In	
  
New	
  Era	
  for	
  Europe."	
  WSJ.com.	
  Wall	
  Street	
  Journal,	
  22	
  Jan.	
  2015.	
  Web.	
  6	
  May	
  2015.	
  
16	
  Ibid.	
  
17	
  Reinhart,	
  Carmen	
  M.,	
  and	
  Kenneth	
  S.	
  Rogoff.	
  "Growth	
  in	
  a	
  Time	
  of	
  Debt."	
  American	
  Economic	
  
Review	
  100.2	
  (2010):	
  573-­‐78.	
  National	
  Bureau	
  of	
  Economic	
  Research.	
  Web.	
  6	
  May	
  2015.	
  
<http://www.nber.org/papers/w15639>.	
  
18	
  British	
  Broadcasting	
  Corporation.	
  "Reinhart	
  and	
  Rogoff	
  Correct	
  Austerity	
  Research	
  Error	
  -­‐	
  
BBC	
  News."	
  BBC.com.	
  BBC,	
  9	
  May	
  2013.	
  Web.	
  7	
  May	
  2015.	
  
19	
  Baum,	
  Anja,	
  Christina	
  Checherita-­‐Westphal,	
  and	
  Philipp	
  Rother.	
  "Debt	
  and	
  Growth:	
  New	
  
Evidence	
  for	
  the	
  Euro	
  Area."	
  European	
  Central	
  Bank	
  Working	
  Papers	
  Series	
  1450	
  (2012):	
  n.	
  
pag.	
  Europa.eu.	
  European	
  Central	
  Bank,	
  July	
  2012.	
  Web.	
  7	
  May	
  2015.	
  
Mitchell	
   12	
  
	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  	
  
20	
  Pescatori,	
  Andrea,	
  Damiano	
  Sandri,	
  and	
  John	
  Simon.	
  "Debt	
  and	
  Growth:	
  Is	
  There	
  a	
  Magic	
  
Threshold?"	
  IMF	
  Working	
  Papers	
  34th	
  ser.	
  14	
  (2014):	
  n.	
  pag.	
  IMF.org.	
  International	
  Monetary	
  
Fund,	
  Feb.	
  2014.	
  Web.	
  5	
  May	
  2015.	
  
21	
  University	
  of	
  Chicago.	
  "Poll	
  Results	
  |	
  IGM	
  Forum."	
  Igmchicago.com.	
  University	
  of	
  Chicago,	
  13	
  
Nov.	
  2012.	
  Web.	
  6	
  May	
  2015.	
  
22	
  Collignon,	
  Stefan,	
  Piero	
  Esposito,	
  and	
  Hannah	
  Lierse.	
  "European	
  Sovereign	
  Bailouts,	
  Political	
  
Risk	
  and	
  the	
  Economic	
  Consequences	
  of	
  Mrs.	
  Merkel."	
  Journal	
  of	
  International	
  Commerce,	
  
Economics	
  and	
  Policy	
  4.2	
  (2013):	
  n.	
  pag.	
  World	
  Scientific.	
  Web.	
  7	
  May	
  2015.	
  
23	
  Duchin,	
  Ran,	
  and	
  Denis	
  Sosyura.	
  "Safer	
  Ratios,	
  Riskier	
  Portfolios:	
  Banks'	
  Response	
  to	
  
Government	
  Aid."	
  Journal	
  of	
  Financial	
  Economics	
  (2014):	
  n.	
  pag.	
  Social	
  Science	
  Research	
  
Network.	
  Web.	
  3	
  May	
  2015.	
  
24	
  Helgi	
  Library.	
  "Bank	
  Assets	
  (As	
  %	
  Of	
  GDP)	
  in	
  Ireland."	
  Helgilibrary.com.	
  Helgi	
  Library,	
  8	
  Mar.	
  
2015.	
  Web.	
  7	
  May	
  2015.	
  
25	
  European	
  Commission.	
  "Ireland's	
  Economic	
  Crisis:	
  How	
  Did	
  It	
  Happen	
  and	
  What	
  Is	
  Being	
  
Done	
  about	
  It?"	
  Europa.eu.	
  European	
  Commission,	
  12	
  June	
  2012.	
  Web.	
  8	
  May	
  2015.	
  
26	
  Trading	
  Economics.	
  "Ireland	
  Government	
  Debt	
  to	
  GDP."	
  Tradingeconomics.com.	
  Trading	
  
Economics,	
  n.d.	
  Web.	
  8	
  May	
  2015.	
  
27	
  Trading	
  Economics.	
  "Ireland	
  Government	
  Bond	
  10Y."	
  Tradingeconomics.com.	
  Trading	
  
Economics,	
  n.d.	
  Web.	
  8	
  May	
  2015.	
  
28	
  Castle,	
  Stephen.	
  "E.C.B.	
  Threatened	
  to	
  End	
  Funding	
  Unless	
  Ireland	
  Took	
  Bailout,	
  Letters	
  
Show."	
  NYTimes.com.	
  The	
  New	
  York	
  Times,	
  07	
  Nov.	
  2014.	
  Web.	
  8	
  May	
  2015.	
  
29	
  Trading	
  Economics.	
  "Ireland	
  GDP	
  Growth	
  Rate."	
  Tradingeconomics.com.	
  Trading	
  Economics,	
  
n.d.	
  Web.	
  8	
  May	
  2015.	
  
30	
  Trading	
  Economics.	
  "Ireland	
  Unemployment	
  Rate."	
  Tradingeconomics.com.	
  Trading	
  
Economics,	
  n.d.	
  Web.	
  8	
  May	
  2015.	
  
31	
  International	
  Labour	
  Organization.	
  Global	
  Wage	
  Report	
  2014/15:	
  Wages	
  and	
  Income	
  
Inequality.	
  Rep.	
  Geneva:	
  International	
  Labour	
  Officer,	
  2015.	
  Ilo.org.	
  International	
  Labour	
  
Organization,	
  2015.	
  Web.	
  7	
  May	
  2015.	
  
32	
  Hannon,	
  Paul.	
  "Ireland's	
  Economy	
  Surges	
  Ahead	
  of	
  Eurozone."	
  WSJ.com.	
  Wall	
  Street	
  Journal,	
  
18	
  Sept.	
  2014.	
  Web.	
  8	
  May	
  2015.	
  
33	
  Trading	
  Economics.	
  "Greece	
  Exports."	
  Tradingeconomics.com.	
  Trading	
  Economics,	
  n.d.	
  Web.	
  
9	
  May	
  2015.	
  
34	
  Eurostat.	
  European	
  Union	
  Goods	
  and	
  Services	
  Exports	
  by	
  Country	
  –	
  Annual	
  Data.	
  2	
  Mar.	
  
2015.	
  Raw	
  data.	
  Europa.eu,	
  Luxembourg.	
  
35	
  Eurostat.	
  European	
  Union	
  Central	
  Government	
  Gross	
  Debt	
  -­‐	
  Annual	
  Data.	
  2	
  Mar.	
  2015.	
  Raw	
  
data.	
  Europa.eu,	
  Luxembourg.	
  
36	
  European	
  Union.	
  European	
  Commission.	
  Economic	
  and	
  Financial	
  Affairs	
  Council	
  
Configuration.	
  Report	
  on	
  Greek	
  Government	
  Deficit	
  and	
  Debt	
  Statistics.	
  By	
  European	
  
Commission.	
  Luxembourg:	
  Office	
  for	
  Official	
  Publications	
  of	
  the	
  European	
  Communities,	
  2010.	
  
Europa.eu.	
  European	
  Commission,	
  8	
  Jan.	
  2010.	
  Web.	
  9	
  May	
  2015.	
  
37	
  Trading	
  Economics.	
  "Greece	
  Unemployment	
  Rate."	
  Tradingeconomics.com.	
  Trading	
  
Economics,	
  n.d.	
  Web.	
  9	
  May	
  2015.	
  
38	
  Trading	
  Economics.	
  "Greece	
  GDP	
  Growth	
  Rate."	
  Tradingeconomics.com.	
  Trading	
  Economics,	
  
n.d.	
  Web.	
  9	
  May	
  2015.	
  
39	
  Spence,	
  Peter.	
  "ECB	
  Doing	
  'Too	
  Little,	
  Too	
  Late'	
  to	
  Rescue	
  Eurozone,	
  Experts	
  Warn."	
  
Telegraph.co.uk.	
  The	
  Telegraph,	
  9	
  Feb.	
  2015.	
  Web.	
  10	
  May	
  2015.	
  
Mitchell	
   13	
  
	
  
	
  
Data	
  Source:	
  European	
  Central	
  Bank	
  
Chart	
  Source:	
  Author	
  
0	
  
5	
  
10	
  
15	
  
20	
  
25	
  
30	
  
35	
  
2015Mar	
  
2014Dec	
  
2014Sep	
  
2014Jun	
  
2014Mar	
  
2013Dec	
  
2013Sep	
  
2013Jun	
  
2013Mar	
  
2012Dec	
  
2012Sep	
  
2012Jun	
  
2012Mar	
  
2011Dec	
  
2011Sep	
  
2011Jun	
  
2011Mar	
  
2010Dec	
  
2010Sep	
  
2010Jun	
  
2010Mar	
  
2009Dec	
  
2009Sep	
  
2009Jun	
  
2009Mar	
  
2008Dec	
  
2008Sep	
  
2008Jun	
  
2008Mar	
  
2007Dec	
  
2007Sep	
  
Interest	
  Rate	
  (%)	
  
Month	
  
Table	
  1	
  –	
  Interest	
  Rates	
  on	
  Eurozone	
  Country	
  Long-­‐Term	
  Bonds	
  
	
  
Austria	
  
Belgium	
  
Germany	
  
Spain	
  
Finland	
  
France	
  
Greece	
  
Ireland	
  
Italy	
  
Netherlands	
  
Portugal	
  
Lehman	
  Brothers	
  
Collapse	
  
Greece	
  Debt	
  
Scandal	
  
Mitchell	
   14	
  
	
  
	
  
Data	
  source:	
  US	
  Census	
  
Chart	
  source:	
  Author	
  
	
  
15000	
  
20000	
  
25000	
  
30000	
  
35000	
  
40000	
  
Jan-­‐06	
  
Mar-­‐06	
  
May-­‐06	
  
Jul-­‐06	
  
Sep-­‐06	
  
Nov-­‐06	
  
Jan-­‐07	
  
Mar-­‐07	
  
May-­‐07	
  
Jul-­‐07	
  
Sep-­‐07	
  
Nov-­‐07	
  
Jan-­‐08	
  
Mar-­‐08	
  
May-­‐08	
  
Jul-­‐08	
  
Sep-­‐08	
  
Nov-­‐08	
  
Jan-­‐09	
  
Mar-­‐09	
  
May-­‐09	
  
Jul-­‐09	
  
Sep-­‐09	
  
Nov-­‐09	
  
Jan-­‐10	
  
Mar-­‐10	
  
May-­‐10	
  
Jul-­‐10	
  
Sep-­‐10	
  
Nov-­‐10	
  
Imports	
  ($millions;	
  not	
  seasonally	
  adjusted)	
   Table	
  2	
  -­‐	
  Value	
  of	
  US	
  Imports	
  by	
  Month	
  
Lehman	
  Brothers	
  
Collapse	
  
Mitchell	
   15	
  
	
  
Data	
  Source:	
  Eurostat	
  
Chart	
  Source:	
  Author	
  
0	
  
10000	
  
20000	
  
30000	
  
40000	
  
50000	
  
60000	
  
70000	
  
2004	
   2005	
   2006	
   2007	
   2008	
   2009	
   2010	
   2011	
   2012	
   2013	
   2014	
  
Value	
  of	
  Exports	
  (Millions	
  of	
  Euros)	
  
Year	
  
Table	
  3	
  -­‐	
  Value	
  of	
  Greek	
  Exports	
  by	
  Year	
  
Export	
  
Shock	
  

More Related Content

What's hot

Europe rejected or recharged
Europe  rejected or recharged Europe  rejected or recharged
Europe rejected or recharged TariqCarrimjee
 
POSITION PAPER: Euro Zone Crisis. Diagnosis and Likely Solutions (ESADEgeo)
POSITION PAPER: Euro Zone Crisis. Diagnosis and Likely Solutions (ESADEgeo)POSITION PAPER: Euro Zone Crisis. Diagnosis and Likely Solutions (ESADEgeo)
POSITION PAPER: Euro Zone Crisis. Diagnosis and Likely Solutions (ESADEgeo)ESADE
 
Euro debt crisis div a
Euro debt crisis div aEuro debt crisis div a
Euro debt crisis div aMohil Poojara
 
European sovereign debt crisis
European sovereign debt crisisEuropean sovereign debt crisis
European sovereign debt crisisPinkesh Jain
 
Euro crisis
Euro crisisEuro crisis
Euro crisisRS P
 
Eurozone debt crises
Eurozone debt crisesEurozone debt crises
Eurozone debt crisesWordpandit
 
Eurozone debt crisis
Eurozone debt crisisEurozone debt crisis
Eurozone debt crisistomarricha
 
Euro Sovereign Debt Crisis
Euro Sovereign Debt CrisisEuro Sovereign Debt Crisis
Euro Sovereign Debt CrisisShikher Kaushik
 
The Political Economy of Fiscal and Monetary Institutions
The Political Economy of Fiscal and Monetary InstitutionsThe Political Economy of Fiscal and Monetary Institutions
The Political Economy of Fiscal and Monetary InstitutionsADEMU_Project
 
20130905 sapirwolff final
20130905 sapirwolff final20130905 sapirwolff final
20130905 sapirwolff finalBruegel
 

What's hot (19)

Unit 2 Gordon
Unit 2 GordonUnit 2 Gordon
Unit 2 Gordon
 
Eurozone crisis
Eurozone crisisEurozone crisis
Eurozone crisis
 
European debt crisis
European debt crisisEuropean debt crisis
European debt crisis
 
Impact of Debt Crisis on EMU
Impact of Debt Crisis on EMUImpact of Debt Crisis on EMU
Impact of Debt Crisis on EMU
 
Europe rejected or recharged
Europe  rejected or recharged Europe  rejected or recharged
Europe rejected or recharged
 
The EU Economic Crisis
The EU Economic CrisisThe EU Economic Crisis
The EU Economic Crisis
 
euro crisis
euro crisiseuro crisis
euro crisis
 
POSITION PAPER: Euro Zone Crisis. Diagnosis and Likely Solutions (ESADEgeo)
POSITION PAPER: Euro Zone Crisis. Diagnosis and Likely Solutions (ESADEgeo)POSITION PAPER: Euro Zone Crisis. Diagnosis and Likely Solutions (ESADEgeo)
POSITION PAPER: Euro Zone Crisis. Diagnosis and Likely Solutions (ESADEgeo)
 
Euro debt crisis div a
Euro debt crisis div aEuro debt crisis div a
Euro debt crisis div a
 
European sovereign debt crisis
European sovereign debt crisisEuropean sovereign debt crisis
European sovereign debt crisis
 
Euro zone crisis ppt
Euro zone crisis pptEuro zone crisis ppt
Euro zone crisis ppt
 
Euro crisis
Euro crisisEuro crisis
Euro crisis
 
Euro crisis
Euro crisis Euro crisis
Euro crisis
 
Euro crisis
Euro crisisEuro crisis
Euro crisis
 
Eurozone debt crises
Eurozone debt crisesEurozone debt crises
Eurozone debt crises
 
Eurozone debt crisis
Eurozone debt crisisEurozone debt crisis
Eurozone debt crisis
 
Euro Sovereign Debt Crisis
Euro Sovereign Debt CrisisEuro Sovereign Debt Crisis
Euro Sovereign Debt Crisis
 
The Political Economy of Fiscal and Monetary Institutions
The Political Economy of Fiscal and Monetary InstitutionsThe Political Economy of Fiscal and Monetary Institutions
The Political Economy of Fiscal and Monetary Institutions
 
20130905 sapirwolff final
20130905 sapirwolff final20130905 sapirwolff final
20130905 sapirwolff final
 

Similar to Euro Crisis Structural Defects and Ineffective Policy

Greece emu
Greece emuGreece emu
Greece emuRyan Cho
 
Greece And Its Relationship With The Eurozone
Greece And Its Relationship With The EurozoneGreece And Its Relationship With The Eurozone
Greece And Its Relationship With The EurozoneMelissa Williams
 
The euro zone crisis jkn-kini
The euro zone crisis jkn-kiniThe euro zone crisis jkn-kini
The euro zone crisis jkn-kiniJK-tiger
 
Item 8 - Bradford_Marzec_White_Paper_Waking_From_The_Euro_Dream
Item 8 - Bradford_Marzec_White_Paper_Waking_From_The_Euro_DreamItem 8 - Bradford_Marzec_White_Paper_Waking_From_The_Euro_Dream
Item 8 - Bradford_Marzec_White_Paper_Waking_From_The_Euro_DreamGraham Allen
 
Lazard Investment Research: Sunset Boulevard, An Interim Report on the Develo...
Lazard Investment Research: Sunset Boulevard, An Interim Report on the Develo...Lazard Investment Research: Sunset Boulevard, An Interim Report on the Develo...
Lazard Investment Research: Sunset Boulevard, An Interim Report on the Develo...LazardLazard
 
Shocking aspectsofmonetaryunion
Shocking aspectsofmonetaryunionShocking aspectsofmonetaryunion
Shocking aspectsofmonetaryunionOldegar Simoes
 
Harvard Kennedy School: Eurozone Study Jan. 2017
Harvard Kennedy School: Eurozone Study Jan. 2017 Harvard Kennedy School: Eurozone Study Jan. 2017
Harvard Kennedy School: Eurozone Study Jan. 2017 chaganomics
 
Understanding the european debt crisis
Understanding the european debt crisisUnderstanding the european debt crisis
Understanding the european debt crisisAmens Corner Capital
 
Pensions and the European Debt Crisis
Pensions and the European Debt CrisisPensions and the European Debt Crisis
Pensions and the European Debt CrisisAegon
 

Similar to Euro Crisis Structural Defects and Ineffective Policy (13)

Greece emu
Greece emuGreece emu
Greece emu
 
Greece And Its Relationship With The Eurozone
Greece And Its Relationship With The EurozoneGreece And Its Relationship With The Eurozone
Greece And Its Relationship With The Eurozone
 
EMUDebtCrisis
EMUDebtCrisisEMUDebtCrisis
EMUDebtCrisis
 
The euro zone crisis jkn-kini
The euro zone crisis jkn-kiniThe euro zone crisis jkn-kini
The euro zone crisis jkn-kini
 
Item 8 - Bradford_Marzec_White_Paper_Waking_From_The_Euro_Dream
Item 8 - Bradford_Marzec_White_Paper_Waking_From_The_Euro_DreamItem 8 - Bradford_Marzec_White_Paper_Waking_From_The_Euro_Dream
Item 8 - Bradford_Marzec_White_Paper_Waking_From_The_Euro_Dream
 
Lazard Investment Research: Sunset Boulevard, An Interim Report on the Develo...
Lazard Investment Research: Sunset Boulevard, An Interim Report on the Develo...Lazard Investment Research: Sunset Boulevard, An Interim Report on the Develo...
Lazard Investment Research: Sunset Boulevard, An Interim Report on the Develo...
 
Seminar3
Seminar3Seminar3
Seminar3
 
Understanding The European Debt Crisis
Understanding The European Debt CrisisUnderstanding The European Debt Crisis
Understanding The European Debt Crisis
 
Shocking aspectsofmonetaryunion
Shocking aspectsofmonetaryunionShocking aspectsofmonetaryunion
Shocking aspectsofmonetaryunion
 
Understanding the european debt crisis
Understanding the european debt crisisUnderstanding the european debt crisis
Understanding the european debt crisis
 
Harvard Kennedy School: Eurozone Study Jan. 2017
Harvard Kennedy School: Eurozone Study Jan. 2017 Harvard Kennedy School: Eurozone Study Jan. 2017
Harvard Kennedy School: Eurozone Study Jan. 2017
 
Understanding the european debt crisis
Understanding the european debt crisisUnderstanding the european debt crisis
Understanding the european debt crisis
 
Pensions and the European Debt Crisis
Pensions and the European Debt CrisisPensions and the European Debt Crisis
Pensions and the European Debt Crisis
 

Euro Crisis Structural Defects and Ineffective Policy

  • 1.               The  Euro  Crisis:     Structural  Defects  and  Ineffective  Policy         By:  Alec  Mitchell   Econ  442,  Professor  Menzie  Chinn   5/11/2015  
  • 2. Mitchell   1   Introduction     While  the  collapse  of  Lehman  Brothers  in  September  of  2008  was  the  actual   explosion  in  the  coal  mine  for  the  United  States,  the  Eurozone  failed  to  view  it  as  they   should  have:  a  canary  for  the  longstanding  gas  leak  that  is  the  imperfect  Euro  currency   union.  Just  over  a  year  later,  Ireland  and  Greece  saw  their  interest  rates  quickly  and   suddenly  rise  past  their  Euro  counterparts  for  the  first  time  since  entering  the  union1   (Table  1).  The  cause  of  the  rise  was  mixed  across  the  board,  reflecting  the  diverse  nature  of   the  Eurozone.  In  Ireland,  the  housing  bubble  crash  looked  eerily  similar  to  the  United   States,  but  was  magnified  by  the  fact  that  Irish  banks  were  larger  in  proportion  to  Irish   GDP,  making  bailouts  more  costly  for  the  small  nation.  For  Greece,  longstanding  high   deficits  and  revelations  as  to  their  actual  levels  of  debt  led  to  uncertainty  in  the  markets.   Along  with  the  rest  of  the  Eurozone,  both  were  hit  by  a  decrease  in  US  imports  from  Europe   and  a  devaluation  of  the  dollar  relative  to  the  Euro  heading  into  2010  (Table  2).   The  Eurozone’s  Problem     In  an  ideal  currency  union,  there  is  high  labor  and  capital  mobility,  risk  smoothing,   and  symmetric  business  cycles  among  regions.  For  the  Eurozone,  however,  only  one  of   these  seems  to  be  true  in  capital  mobility.  While  the  zone  rode  out  the  beginning  of  the  US   crisis,  cracks  began  to  show  within  a  year.  Austerity  policies  put  in  place  to  solve  high  debts   have  failed  to  stem  the  crisis,  and  a  lack  of  unified  monetary  policy  has  crippled  struggling   countries.  The  problem  now  facing  the  Eurozone  is  one  of  existential  proportions:  can  it   become  a  more  optimal  currency  zone?  If  not,  should  it,  and  can  it,  survive?      
  • 3. Mitchell   2   Optimality  of  the  Zone     The  Eurozone’s  performance  on  the  first  condition  of  optimality,  labor  mobility,   pales  in  comparison  to  the  United  States.  Blanchard  and  Katz’s  prescient  1992  paper   described  the  difficulty  that  the  Eurozone  would  have  in  terms  of  labor  mobility;  they   showed  that  individual  US  states  tend  to  recover  from  asymmetric  shocks  through   moderate  to  high  labor  mobility.2  In  fact,  a  2014  European  Commission  report  estimated   that  cross-­‐country  mobility  in  the  EU  was  .2  percent,  less  than  one-­‐tenth  of  the  2.7  percent   state-­‐to-­‐state  mobility  in  the  US.3  This  does  not  bode  well  for  the  Eurozone  considering  that   the  pressures  faced  by  individual  depressed  countries  are  due,  in  large  part,  to  external   demand  imbalances.  A  2015  working  paper  by  Emmanuel  Farhi  and  Ivan  Werning  shows   that  mobility  out  of  depressed  regions  has  a  significantly  positive  effect  on  those  who   decide  to  stay,  but  only  when  the  source  of  demand  imbalances  is  external  (such  as  the   current  Euro  Crisis).4  In  sum,  the  unique  structure  of  the  Eurozone  puts  it  at  a  disadvantage   for  the  first  pillar  of  optimality,  a  condition  that  may  need  to  change  if  it  is  to  survive.     The  strongest  area  for  the  Eurozone  is  capital  mobility,  with  both  historical  and   current  trade  agreements  providing  a  strong  base.  The  1957  Treaty  of  Rome,  a  precursor  to   the  eventual  Treaty  of  Maastricht,  created  the  European  Economic  Community,  which   provided  for  common  goods  markets  and  customs  rates.  The  treaty  was  a  foundation  on   which  the  future  Eurozone  established  strong  capital  mobility.  Authority  over  the  customs   union  was  transferred  to  the  European  Union  after  its  inception,  and  was  expanded  to   include  all  member  states.  Additionally,  the  introduction  of  a  single  currency  has  made   transfer  of  capital  easier,  to  the  tune  of  an  approximate  10  percent  increase.5  
  • 4. Mitchell   3     Perhaps  the  Eurozone’s  trickiest  yet  most  necessary  problem  to  change,  risk   smoothing  across  countries  is  notably  absent  in  the  Eurozone.  Ironically,  the  Eurozone   resembles  the  short-­‐lived  Articles  of  Confederation  in  the  United  States,  with  the  central   authority  unable  to  implement  many  fiscal  or  monetary  policies  without  support  from   member  states.  Unlike  the  current  United  States  system,  whereby  the  federal  government   can  shift  tax  burdens  and  benefits  to  states  hit  by  asymmetric  shocks,  the  Eurozone  is  not   set  up  to  complete  such  actions.  The  supremacy  of  individual  members  over  the  European   Parliament  and  Central  Bank  puts  a  major  damper  on  the  ability  to  shift  benefits  around   the  Union.  Individual  member  states  would  need  to  use  their  own  tax  receipts  to  support   failing  countries,  something  politically  difficult  for  national  legislatures.  Indeed,  the   European  Fiscal  Compact  forces  members  to  keep  their  deficits  under  3  percent  or  face   fines,  and  Germany  has  so  far  stood  strong  in  refusing  the  most  recent  bailout  offers  from   Greece.6  On  the  monetary  policy  front,  quantitative  easing  has  long  been  off  the  table  due  to   both  structural  EU  requirements  and  German  opposition.7  Simply  put,  current  fiscal  and   monetary  policies  do  not  align  with  necessary  structures  required  for  an  optimal  currency   union.     The  last  problem  facing  the  Eurozone  is  the  asymmetric  business  cycles  facing   member  states.  A  2008  research  paper  estimated  that  there  were  two  groups  of  countries:   a  core  and  a  periphery.  The  core  consisted  of  Germany,  France,  The  Netherlands,  and   Finland  (among  others),  while  the  periphery  was  rounded  out  by  Greece,  Ireland,  Portugal,   and  Spain.1  In  addition  to  finding  that  both  groups  are  indeed  out  of  cycle,  the  researchers   also  found  that  the  Euro  has  done  little  to  bring  them  into  alignment.8  As  such,  it  is  difficult                                                                                                                   1  The  last  GIIPS  country,  Italy,  was  the  only  one  included  within  the  core  group  
  • 5. Mitchell   4   for  a  central  bank  to  utilize  many  available  monetary  policies  in  a  way  that  can  help  buoy   the  struggling  periphery  countries,  while  not  also  harming  the  stable  core  countries.   How  the  Crisis  Has  Played  Out   Eurozone  Policy     The  Treaty  of  Lisbon  and  previous  pacts  in  the  EU  impose  significant  restrictions  on   Euro-­‐wide  policy  and  place  heavy  burdens  on  member  states  to  keep  their  financial   conditions  within  certain  bounds.  Article  123  imposes  a  prohibition  on  the  “direct”   purchase  by  the  ECB  of  “(Union  Institution)  debt  instruments,”  and  many  have  interpreted   this  to  preclude  any  monetary  financing  whatsoever.  9  Article  124  prohibits  privileged   access  to  financial  institutions  for  any  union  institution.10  In  addition,  article  125  imposes   severe  restrictions  on  the  ability  of  the  EU  to  “bail  out”  any  government  within  the  EU.11   The  European  Fiscal  Compact,  signed  in  2012,  places  tighter  controls  on  the  longstanding   policy  that  member  countries  must  have  less  than  3  percent  deficit  to  GDP  and  60  percent   debt  to  GDP  ratios.12  Finally,  all  monetary  policy  is  complicated  by  the  fact  that  the  ECB’s   primary  job  is  limited  to  keeping  inflation  close  to  2  percent.13     These  policies,  while  not  inherently  meant  to  impede  recovery,  clash  with  what   many  economists  consider  the  best  set  of  policies  in  a  recession.  The  most  confusing  policy   stance  is  the  EU’s  resistance  to  quantitative  easing  in  the  sovereign  bond  and  securities   markets.  Most  advanced  economies  rely  on  countercyclical  monetary  policy  to  smooth  the   business  cycle,  encouraging  growth  in  troughs  and  putting  on  the  brakes  during  peaks.14   Such  action  in  recessions  can  lower  interest  rates  by  driving  up  the  demand  in  sovereign   bond  markets,  which  have  seen  skyrocketing  interest  rates  for  Ireland  and  Greece.   However,  Article  123  and  the  ECB’s  own  instructions  effectively  limit  their  ability  to  enact  
  • 6. Mitchell   5   any  such  policy,  even  as  the  crisis  has  leapt  to  historic  proportions  across  the  globe  and  EU.   Finally,  only  two  months  ago,  years  after  the  crisis  began,  the  ECB  began  a  €1.1  trillion   secondary  market  bond-­‐buying  program,  now  under  intense  political  and  legal   controversy.15  So  why  was  policy  not  changed?  In  short,  political  considerations  trumped   economic  theory.  Germany,  the  economic  bedrock  of  the  Eurozone,  has  flat  out  refused  to   accept  such  relief  to  debt  stricken  countries.  Both  of  their  ECB  board  members  have  openly   opposed  such  actions,  and  Chancellor  Angela  Merkel  has  expressed  her  worry  that  such   actions  will  allow  distressed  countries  to  delay  or  even  fail  to  enact  deficit-­‐cutting   reforms.16     These  debt  reforms,  embedded  within  the  European  Fiscal  Compact,  go  against  a   much  more  controversial  area  of  economic  theory.  In  order  for  countries  such  as  Ireland   and  Greece  to  hit  the  3  percent  deficit  and  60  percent  debt  marks,  higher  taxes  and/or   extreme  austerity  measures  have  to  be  implemented.  Some  decision  makers  used  a  widely   cited  research  paper  by  Reinhart  and  Rogoff  as  empirical  evidence  that  high  debt  leads  to   slower  growth,  therefore  vindicating  the  Eurozone’s  strict  policies.17  However,  many   economists  criticized  the  paper,  and  the  authors  were  forced  to  clarify  that  the  two  were   found  to  be  “associated,”  not  necessary  cause  and  effect.18  Yet,  other  research  has  found   that  debt  can  actually  have  a  positive  effect  on  GDP  growth,  up  to  certain  points.19  Even   further,  some  research  has  found  no  threshold  at  which  GDP  growth  is  hampered  by   additional  debt.20  So  what  is  the  correct  policy  choice  here?  The  general  consensus  in  the   economic  realm  is  that  higher  deficits  and  debt  in  the  short  run  can  certainly  have  positive   effects  on  growth,  much  in  line  with  the  Keynesian  aggregate  demand  models.  The  most   uncertainty  occurs,  however,  on  whether  there  is  a  certain  level  of  debt  that  starts  to  
  • 7. Mitchell   6   impede  growth  in  the  long  run.  Therefore,  it  seems  likely  that  the  EU  policy  here  is  likewise   counter  to  what  should  be  pursued  in  recessed  economies,  but  the  evidence  is  not  as  firmly   grounded  as  is  countercyclical  monetary  policy.     The  last  controversial  Eurozone  recessionary  policy  is  the  prohibition  on  most  bail-­‐ outs.  Unlike  countercyclical  and  austerity  policies,  the  evidence  on  bail-­‐outs  is  decidedly   mixed,  with  economists  landing  on  both  ends  of  the  scale.  On  one  hand,  when  assessing  the   effects  of  the  US  bailout,  a  University  of  Chicago  forum  polled  49  leading  economists,  who   on  average  agreed  that  its  benefits  outweighed  the  costs,  that  unemployment  was  lower  as   a  result,  and  that  businesses  were  not  be  incentivized  to  harm  the  economy  further.21   Additionally,  empirical  research  has  shown  that  not  only  are  bailouts  necessary  to  prevent   a  banking  crisis  which  would  wreak  havoc  on  an  economy,  but  even  that  Chancellor   Merkel’s  strong  resistance  to  such  policies  led  to  higher  bailout  costs  for  distressed   countries.22  On  the  other  hand,  research  of  the  US  bailout  has  found  that  banks  did  end  up   having  riskier  portfolios  after  they  were  bailed  out,  evidence  of  a  moral  hazard.23  What  is   seen  overall  is  that  economic  theory  tends  to  agree  that  a  bailout  of  some  undercapitalized   financial  institutions  is  necessary  to  avoid  further  economic  shock,  but  some  economists   show  that  there  is  proof  that  those  institutions  continue  the  same  risky  behavior.  Here,   Chancellor  Merkel’s  concerns  about  moral  hazard  find  stronger  ground.  Bailouts  seem  to  be   beneficial  to  an  economy  when  they  include  strong  regulations  to  prevent  mistakes  from   happening  again.  However,  Germany’s  insistence  for  bailouts  paired  with  strict  austerity   measures  muddles  recovery.     So,  how  do  these  policies  fit  within  specific  Eurozone  countries?  Below,  the   examples  of  Ireland  and  Greece  are  considered.  Irish  banks,  second  largest  in  the  world  in  
  • 8. Mitchell   7   terms  of  GDP,  were  hit  hard  by  the  housing  bubble  and  their  economy  was  the  first  to   tumble.  Ireland  accepted  a  contentious  bailout  with  the  strict  austerity  that  Germany   wanted,  and  their  economy  has  recovered  in  part.  Greece,  bogged  down  by  a  drop  in   exports,  bank  bailouts,  and  high  interest  rates,  was  forced  to  implement  deep  austerity  in   accordance  with  bailout  partners.  Their  economy,  however,  has  turned  to  shambles.   Impact  on  Ireland     Ireland  was  hit  hardest  by  the  mortgage  and  financial  crisis.  Irish  banks,  with   increased  availability  of  capital  from  short  term  lending,  increased  their  balance  sheets  by   enormous  amounts.  In  2008,  Irish  banks  held  assets  worth  783  percent  of  GDP,  second  to   only  Luxembourg.24  The  vast  majority  of  these  assets  were  held  in  property,  while  at  the   same  time,  the  Irish  government  increased  spending  and  relied  more  heavily  on  property   taxes  to  make  up  government  revenue.  As  a  result,  in  2006  property  taxes  reached  of  peak   of  almost  20  percent  of  total  Irish  tax  revenue.25  This  reliance  on  property  by  both  the  Irish   financial  institutions  and  government  led  to  a  perfect  storm  as  the  housing  bubble  burst.       When  the  US  crisis  hit,  housing  prices  fell  and  borrowers  defaulted  on  payments.   The  short  term  borrowing  that  Irish  banks  had  so  heavily  relied  on  to  increase  their   balance  sheets  began  to  dry  up,  limiting  options  for  liquidity  as  the  banks  began  to  feel  the   squeeze.  As  banks  used  up  their  available  capital,  the  Irish  government  stepped  in  and   guaranteed  to  cover  the  liabilities  of  the  struggling  institutions.  However,  in  conjunction   with  sudden  structural  deficits  due  to  a  plunge  in  property  tax  revenue,  Irish  debt  soared   from  25  percent  of  GDP  in  2008  to  over  111  percent  by  2012.26  At  the  same  time,  Irish   yields  increased  from  4  percent  in  2008  to  almost  12  percent  by  the  middle  of  2011,   making  additional  borrowing  too  costly.27  
  • 9. Mitchell   8     The  one-­‐dimensional  scope  of  the  Irish  crisis  and  the  nature  of  their  exports  made   the  path  to  growth  difficult,  yet  simpler  than  Greece.  In  response  to  the  banking  and   emerging  government  debt  crisis,  Ireland  was  essentially  forced  into  a  European   Union/International  Monetary  Fund  bailout  by  the  ECB.28  The  recovery  has  since  been  slow   and  inconsistent.  Ireland’s  GDP  grew  3.2  percent  in  Q4  2012,  then  dropped  3.7  percent  the   next  quarter.  It  had  2  percent+  growth  in  Q3  2013  and  Q1  2014,  then  leveled  off  to  0.5   percent  in  the  last  two  quarters  of  2014.29  Unemployment  remains  at  10  percent,  wages  are   below  2007  levels,  and  consumer  spending  growth  lags  at  0.3  percent,  in  part  due  to  higher   taxes  implemented  to  comply  with  austerity  requirements.30,31,32  So,  while  the  bailout   certainly  aided  the  Irish  economy,  the  austerity  measures  possibly  hampered  recovery,   with  continued  low  consumer  spending,  low  growth  in  wages,  and  high  unemployment.   Impact  on  Greece     Unlike  Ireland,  which  was  impacted  mostly  by  the  banking  crash  and  housing   bubble,  Greece  was  hit  hardest  by  a  dramatic  drop  in  exports,  high  government  debt,  and  a   bookkeeping  scandal  that  scarred  the  government’s  credibility.  Greece’s  exports  are  mainly   low  value  raw  materials,  while  among  Greece’s  largest  trading  partners  are  Italy,  Turkey,   and  Cyprus,  all  hit  hardest  by  the  global  recession.33  Greece’s  exports  plummeted  21%  from   2008  to  2009,  only  recovering  to  their  2008  level  in  2014  (Table  3).34  Greece  also  faced  a   skyrocketing  level  of  government  debt:  from  2005-­‐2010,  their  debt  rose  from  100  percent   to  148  percent  of  GDP.35  With  a  disappearance  of  risk  and  interest  rates  tied  to  the  Euro   average,  Greece  was  able  to  borrow  large  amounts  of  money  at  what  turned  out  to  be   insanely  cheap  prices.  That  changed  when,  in  early  January,  2010,  the  European   Commission  released  a  shocking  report  that  accused  Greece  of  falsifying  records  to  cover  
  • 10. Mitchell   9   up  true  debt  levels.36  Within  one  year,  Greece’s  bond  yields  rose  from  6  percent  to  9.5   percent,  and  peaked  at  29.2  percent  in  early  2012  (Table  1).     With  skyrocketing  bond  yields,  Greece  was  hit  by  both  a  drop  in  tax  receipts   combined  with  the  inability  to  borrow  at  reasonable  prices.  Greece  was  given  two  bailouts   as  a  result  of  their  rising  debt  and  growth  crisis,  one  in  May  2010  and  another  in  July  2011.   Both  programs,  jointly  administered  by  the  EU,  ECB,  and  IMF2,  required  deep  austerity  cuts.   The  Greek  government  did  indeed  reduce  government  spending,  with  seven  successive   austerity  plans  from  2010-­‐2013,  cutting  public  workers’  pay,  overtime,  and  jobs,  while   raising  and  enforcing  existing  taxes  to  increase  receipts.  However,  unlike  Ireland’s   moderate  recovery,  Greece  plunged.  GDP  fell  every  quarter  from  2010-­‐2014,  110,000   businesses  declared  bankruptcy,  and  unemployment  rose  from  10  percent  to  27   percent.37,38  The  drop  in  public  sector  and  private  sector  employment  led  to  lower  tax   receipts,  and  massive  protests  led  to  even  lower  productivity  and  political  chaos.  With  an   inability  to  borrow  on  the  bond  market  and  pressures  from  the  bailout  troika,  Greece   continued  to  cut,  and  their  economy  continued  to  fall.  Only  recently,  in  January  2015,  did   Greece’s  anti-­‐austerity  party  SYRIZA  sweep  into  power,  promising  to  undo  the  austerity   measures  implemented  over  the  past  five  years.     The  Eurozone’s  policies  had  an  even  greater  effect  on  Greece  than  Ireland,  and   played  a  large  part  in  their  deep  recession.  First,  the  prohibition  on  countercyclical   monetary  policy  prevented  Greece  from  spending  money  on  a  stimulus  package  like  the   United  States.  Second,  the  ECB’s  decision  not  to  devalue  the  Euro  meant  that  the  drop  in   Greek  exports  had  no  cushion.  Third,  the  bailouts  and  their  strict  austerity  provisions                                                                                                                   2  The  troika  partnership  was  formed  for  Ireland  and  Greece  in  part  because  of  the  severe   restrictions  placed  on  bailouts  by  Article  125  
  • 11. Mitchell   10   forced  Greece  to  cut  spending  by  massive  amounts,  in  the  hopes  that  international   investors  would  lower  bond  yields.  Quite  simply,  it  did  not  work.  The  drop  in  aggregate   demand  from  lower  government  spending  led  to  a  falling  GDP  and  higher  unemployment,   as  the  classical  Keynesian  model  predicts.  Greece  also  did  not  see  lower  sovereign  bond   interest  rates  until  mid-­‐2013,  so  borrowing  was  out  of  the  question.  While  SYRIZA’s   success  has  caused  a  rise  in  interest  rates  past  10  percent,  the  ECB’s  decision  to  finally   implement  a  quantitative  easing  program  should  help  dull  the  effects.  However,  many   economists  worry  that  the  plan  is  “too  little  too  late”,  and  that  the  Greek  economy  is  stuck   with  slow  growth  for  years  to  come.39   Conclusion     The  Eurozone  crisis’s  origins  can  be  blamed  partially  on  the  United  States,  but  the   slow  recovery  of  countries  like  Ireland  and  Greece  is  entirely  due  to  the  zone’s  optimality,   poor  government  management,  and  ineffective  EU  policies.  The  Euro  currency  union  has   low  labor  mobility,  poor  fiscal  policy,  and  asymmetric  business  cycles.  These  three  failures   have  led  to  the  current  crisis,  wherein  the  Eurozone  has  faced  its  biggest  test  yet.  At  the   same  time,  some  union  members  allowed  their  economic  situations  to  become  unstable.     Ireland’s  banks  ballooned  past  reasonable  sizes  and  Greece’s  debt  passed  100  percent  of   GDP.  When  the  crash  hit,  ECB  policies  with  regards  to  quantitative  easing,  deficit  reduction,   and  bailouts  slowed  their  recovery.  While  Ireland  has  gained  back  some  of  the  economic   indicators  it  lost  during  its  crisis,  severe  structural  problems  remain.  In  Greece,  the  policies   have  led  to  an  outright  depression.  Even  though  the  ECB’s  monetary  policy  may  finally  be   catching  up,  the  road  to  recovery  looks  long  and  tenuous.    
  • 12. Mitchell   11                                                                                                                   1  European  Central  Bank,  and  European  Commission.  Long-­‐term  interest  rate  statistics  for  EU   Member  States.  14  Apr.  2015.  Raw  data.   Https://www.ecb.europa.eu/stats/money/long/html/index.en.html,  Frankfurt.   2  Blanchard,  Olivier  Jean,  Lawrence  F.  Katz,  Robert  E.  Hall,  and  Barry  Eichengreen.  "Regional   Evolutions."  Brookings  Papers  on  Economic  Activity  1992.1  (1992):  n.  pag.  Harvard  Scholar.   Web.  4  May  2015.   3  European  Union.  European  Commission.  Directorate-­‐General  for  Economic  and  Financial   Affairs.  Labour  Mobility  and  Labour  Market  Adjustment  in  the  EU.  By  Alfonso  Arpaia,  Aron  Kiss,   Cees  Diks,  Balazs  Palvolgyi,  and  Alessandro  Turrini.  Luxembourg:  Publications  Office,  2015.   Europa.eu.  European  Commission,  Dec.  2014.  Web.  3  May  2015.   4  Farhi,  Emmanuel,  and  Iván  Werning.  "Labor  Mobility  Within  Currency  Unions."  National   Bureau  of  Economic  Research  (2014):  n.  pag.  NBER.  Web.  7  May  2015.   <http://www.nber.org/papers/w20105>.   5  Baldwin,  Richard.  "The  Euro's  Trade  Effects."  European  Central  Bank  Working  Papers  Series   594  (2006):  n.  pag.  Europa.eu.  Web.  7  May  2015.   6  Monaghan,  Angela.  "Germany  Rejects  Greek  Bailout  Plan  -­‐  As  It  Happened."  The  Guardian.  The   Guardian,  19  Feb.  2015.  Web.  3  May  2015.   7  European  Central  Bank.  "Fiscal  Policies."  Europa.eu.  European  Central  Bank,  n.d.  Web.  4  May   2015.   8  Giannone,  Domenico,  Michele  Lenza,  and  Lucrezia  Reichlin.  "Business  Cycles  in  the  Euro   Area."  National  Bureau  of  Economic  Research  (2008):  n.  pag.  NBER.  Web.  4  May  2015.   <http://www.nber.org/papers/w14529>.   9  Eurostep,  and  EEPA.  "Article  123."  The  Lisbon  Treaty.  Eurostep  -­‐  EEPA,  2008.  Web.  5  May   2015.   10  Eurostep,  and  EEPA.  "Article  124."  The  Lisbon  Treaty.  Eurostep  -­‐  EEPA,  2008.  Web.  5  May   2015.   11  Eurostep,  and  EEPA.  "Article  125."  The  Lisbon  Treaty.  Eurostep  -­‐  EEPA,  2008.  Web.  5  May   2015.   12  European  Central  Bank.  "A  Fiscal  Compact  For  A  Stronger  Economic  and  Monetary  Union."   ECB  Articles  (2012):  79-­‐94.  Europa.eu.  ECB,  May  2012.  Web.  5  May  2015.   13  European  Central  Bank.  "Monetary  Policy."  Europa.eu.  ECB,  n.d.  Web.  6  May  2015.   14  Coulibaly,  Brahima.  "The  Long  Road  to  Countercyclical  Monetary  Policy  in  Emerging  Market   Economies."  FederalReserve.gov.  Board  of  Governors  of  the  Federal  Reserve  System,  3  Dec.   2013.  Web.  5  May  2015.   15  Blackstone,  Brian,  Paul  Hannon,  and  Marcus  Walker.  "Aggressive  ECB  Stimulus  Ushers  In   New  Era  for  Europe."  WSJ.com.  Wall  Street  Journal,  22  Jan.  2015.  Web.  6  May  2015.   16  Ibid.   17  Reinhart,  Carmen  M.,  and  Kenneth  S.  Rogoff.  "Growth  in  a  Time  of  Debt."  American  Economic   Review  100.2  (2010):  573-­‐78.  National  Bureau  of  Economic  Research.  Web.  6  May  2015.   <http://www.nber.org/papers/w15639>.   18  British  Broadcasting  Corporation.  "Reinhart  and  Rogoff  Correct  Austerity  Research  Error  -­‐   BBC  News."  BBC.com.  BBC,  9  May  2013.  Web.  7  May  2015.   19  Baum,  Anja,  Christina  Checherita-­‐Westphal,  and  Philipp  Rother.  "Debt  and  Growth:  New   Evidence  for  the  Euro  Area."  European  Central  Bank  Working  Papers  Series  1450  (2012):  n.   pag.  Europa.eu.  European  Central  Bank,  July  2012.  Web.  7  May  2015.  
  • 13. Mitchell   12                                                                                                                                                                                                                                                                                                                                                                         20  Pescatori,  Andrea,  Damiano  Sandri,  and  John  Simon.  "Debt  and  Growth:  Is  There  a  Magic   Threshold?"  IMF  Working  Papers  34th  ser.  14  (2014):  n.  pag.  IMF.org.  International  Monetary   Fund,  Feb.  2014.  Web.  5  May  2015.   21  University  of  Chicago.  "Poll  Results  |  IGM  Forum."  Igmchicago.com.  University  of  Chicago,  13   Nov.  2012.  Web.  6  May  2015.   22  Collignon,  Stefan,  Piero  Esposito,  and  Hannah  Lierse.  "European  Sovereign  Bailouts,  Political   Risk  and  the  Economic  Consequences  of  Mrs.  Merkel."  Journal  of  International  Commerce,   Economics  and  Policy  4.2  (2013):  n.  pag.  World  Scientific.  Web.  7  May  2015.   23  Duchin,  Ran,  and  Denis  Sosyura.  "Safer  Ratios,  Riskier  Portfolios:  Banks'  Response  to   Government  Aid."  Journal  of  Financial  Economics  (2014):  n.  pag.  Social  Science  Research   Network.  Web.  3  May  2015.   24  Helgi  Library.  "Bank  Assets  (As  %  Of  GDP)  in  Ireland."  Helgilibrary.com.  Helgi  Library,  8  Mar.   2015.  Web.  7  May  2015.   25  European  Commission.  "Ireland's  Economic  Crisis:  How  Did  It  Happen  and  What  Is  Being   Done  about  It?"  Europa.eu.  European  Commission,  12  June  2012.  Web.  8  May  2015.   26  Trading  Economics.  "Ireland  Government  Debt  to  GDP."  Tradingeconomics.com.  Trading   Economics,  n.d.  Web.  8  May  2015.   27  Trading  Economics.  "Ireland  Government  Bond  10Y."  Tradingeconomics.com.  Trading   Economics,  n.d.  Web.  8  May  2015.   28  Castle,  Stephen.  "E.C.B.  Threatened  to  End  Funding  Unless  Ireland  Took  Bailout,  Letters   Show."  NYTimes.com.  The  New  York  Times,  07  Nov.  2014.  Web.  8  May  2015.   29  Trading  Economics.  "Ireland  GDP  Growth  Rate."  Tradingeconomics.com.  Trading  Economics,   n.d.  Web.  8  May  2015.   30  Trading  Economics.  "Ireland  Unemployment  Rate."  Tradingeconomics.com.  Trading   Economics,  n.d.  Web.  8  May  2015.   31  International  Labour  Organization.  Global  Wage  Report  2014/15:  Wages  and  Income   Inequality.  Rep.  Geneva:  International  Labour  Officer,  2015.  Ilo.org.  International  Labour   Organization,  2015.  Web.  7  May  2015.   32  Hannon,  Paul.  "Ireland's  Economy  Surges  Ahead  of  Eurozone."  WSJ.com.  Wall  Street  Journal,   18  Sept.  2014.  Web.  8  May  2015.   33  Trading  Economics.  "Greece  Exports."  Tradingeconomics.com.  Trading  Economics,  n.d.  Web.   9  May  2015.   34  Eurostat.  European  Union  Goods  and  Services  Exports  by  Country  –  Annual  Data.  2  Mar.   2015.  Raw  data.  Europa.eu,  Luxembourg.   35  Eurostat.  European  Union  Central  Government  Gross  Debt  -­‐  Annual  Data.  2  Mar.  2015.  Raw   data.  Europa.eu,  Luxembourg.   36  European  Union.  European  Commission.  Economic  and  Financial  Affairs  Council   Configuration.  Report  on  Greek  Government  Deficit  and  Debt  Statistics.  By  European   Commission.  Luxembourg:  Office  for  Official  Publications  of  the  European  Communities,  2010.   Europa.eu.  European  Commission,  8  Jan.  2010.  Web.  9  May  2015.   37  Trading  Economics.  "Greece  Unemployment  Rate."  Tradingeconomics.com.  Trading   Economics,  n.d.  Web.  9  May  2015.   38  Trading  Economics.  "Greece  GDP  Growth  Rate."  Tradingeconomics.com.  Trading  Economics,   n.d.  Web.  9  May  2015.   39  Spence,  Peter.  "ECB  Doing  'Too  Little,  Too  Late'  to  Rescue  Eurozone,  Experts  Warn."   Telegraph.co.uk.  The  Telegraph,  9  Feb.  2015.  Web.  10  May  2015.  
  • 14. Mitchell   13       Data  Source:  European  Central  Bank   Chart  Source:  Author   0   5   10   15   20   25   30   35   2015Mar   2014Dec   2014Sep   2014Jun   2014Mar   2013Dec   2013Sep   2013Jun   2013Mar   2012Dec   2012Sep   2012Jun   2012Mar   2011Dec   2011Sep   2011Jun   2011Mar   2010Dec   2010Sep   2010Jun   2010Mar   2009Dec   2009Sep   2009Jun   2009Mar   2008Dec   2008Sep   2008Jun   2008Mar   2007Dec   2007Sep   Interest  Rate  (%)   Month   Table  1  –  Interest  Rates  on  Eurozone  Country  Long-­‐Term  Bonds     Austria   Belgium   Germany   Spain   Finland   France   Greece   Ireland   Italy   Netherlands   Portugal   Lehman  Brothers   Collapse   Greece  Debt   Scandal  
  • 15. Mitchell   14       Data  source:  US  Census   Chart  source:  Author     15000   20000   25000   30000   35000   40000   Jan-­‐06   Mar-­‐06   May-­‐06   Jul-­‐06   Sep-­‐06   Nov-­‐06   Jan-­‐07   Mar-­‐07   May-­‐07   Jul-­‐07   Sep-­‐07   Nov-­‐07   Jan-­‐08   Mar-­‐08   May-­‐08   Jul-­‐08   Sep-­‐08   Nov-­‐08   Jan-­‐09   Mar-­‐09   May-­‐09   Jul-­‐09   Sep-­‐09   Nov-­‐09   Jan-­‐10   Mar-­‐10   May-­‐10   Jul-­‐10   Sep-­‐10   Nov-­‐10   Imports  ($millions;  not  seasonally  adjusted)   Table  2  -­‐  Value  of  US  Imports  by  Month   Lehman  Brothers   Collapse  
  • 16. Mitchell   15     Data  Source:  Eurostat   Chart  Source:  Author   0   10000   20000   30000   40000   50000   60000   70000   2004   2005   2006   2007   2008   2009   2010   2011   2012   2013   2014   Value  of  Exports  (Millions  of  Euros)   Year   Table  3  -­‐  Value  of  Greek  Exports  by  Year   Export   Shock