SlideShare a Scribd company logo
1 of 105
Counseling Disposition Reflection Worksheet
Directions: Review the dispositions document and select three
dispositions that you currently meet. Complete the chart by
listing the dispositions met as well as a description of how you
meet the disposition. Include a citation and paraphrase the
definition. Please note: you do not need to be actively
practicing to complete this worksheet.
Disposition and Definition
Description of how the disposition is met (75-100 words)
1.
2.
3.
Directions: Now that you have identified dispositions that you
currently meet, review the disposition document again and
consider any dispositions that you do not meet. Complete the
chart below by adding the two dispositions you do not meet as
well as a preliminary plan in regards to how you plan to
improve the identified dispositions.
Disposition and Definition
Description of how you plan to improve the disposition
(75-100 words)
1.
2.
© 2016. Grand Canyon University. All Rights Reserved.
© 2014. Grand Canyon University. All Rights Reserved.
5Coalition Formation in Eastern Europe
LEGISLATIVE STUDIES QUARTERLY, XXXII, 1, February
2007 5
JAMES N. DRUCKMAN
ANDREW ROBERTS
Northwestern University
Communist Successor Parties
And Coalition Formation
In Eastern Europe
One of the most distinctive features of new democracies is the
presence of
political parties associated with the old, repressive regime. This
article investigates
whether or not the Eastern European variant of these parties,
which we call communist
successor parties (CSPs), has affected coalition pol itics. It finds
that CSPs do have
significant effects on the dynamics of coalition formation. CSPs
are less likely than
other parties to be included in governing coalitions; coalitions
that include CSPs are
more likely to be oversized (that is, to include superfluous
parties); and CSPs that
make it into government are penalized, insofar as they receive
less than their fair
share of governing portfolios. We attribute these results to the
salience of the regime
divide—the affective dislike of many citizens for the legacies of
communism. Our
results extend research on coalition behavior to Eastern
European contexts and show
how affective dislike combined with vote-seeking motivations
can affect governing
behavior.
How do coalitions form and function in new democracies? Most
existing theories suggest that coalition formation in these
countries
should be driven by the same factors as in established
democracies:
the size and ideology of parties and the institutional framework
in
which they operate (see Martin and Stevenson 2001 for a
summary of
theories).
In this article, we look at one significant fact about new
democracies
that may produce a different sort of coalition politics. Most new
democracies are distinguished by the presence of successors to
the
former ruling parties. These successors may simply be accepted
as
normal players in the democratic game, but there are good
reasons to
believe they will be treated differently by other parties. After
all, the
successor parties are associated with regimes that, at best,
restricted
fundamental human rights and, at worst, murdered or
imprisoned
significant portions of their countries’ populations. It is thus
reasonable
6 James N. Druckman and Andrew Roberts
to expect that these parties will be seen as more than si mply
bearers of
legislative strength and ideology.
To address this issue, we examine coalition politics in 15
Eastern
European countries. Specifically, we studied the effect on
coalition
formation of what we call communist successor parties (CSPs),
the
parties that are the organizational successors to the former
ruling
communist parties.
We focused on three aspects of coalition politics: Do CSPs
enter
government to the same extent as other parties? Do the
governments
that CSPs enter differ from governments composed of other
parties?
And are CSPs allocated a proportional share of ministries when
they
enter government? In all three cases, we found evidence that
CSPs are
treated differently than other parties, even when we controlled
for their
legislative strength and ideology.
We believe that these anomalies stem from a combination of
affective dislike on the part of voters and party activists for
CSPs and
the vote-seeking motivations of party leaders. Party leaders
appear to
follow the lead of their electorates and party activists in
shunning CSPs
or limiting the CSPs’ influence on politics.
Our findings are particularly interesting because there has been
relatively little study of coalition formation in new
democracies.
Consistent with recent institutional theories of coalition
behavior (for
example, Martin and Stevenson 2001 and Strøm, Budge, and
Laver
1994), the results imply that understanding coalitional politics
requires
contextual knowledge about the substance of national politics.
Specifically, our findings suggest that scholars should pay more
attention to the affective attitudes of party electorates and elites
toward
rival parties. In cases where there is strong affective dislike of a
particular party, vote-seeking motivations may be as, or perhaps
even
more, important than office- and policy-seeking motivations of
parties.
I. Communist Successor Parties
Few topics in postcommunist politics have been studied as
intensively as communist successor parties, the parties that are
the
organizational successors to the old ruling parties. A review of
the
literature on this topic reveals at least two books, two edited
volumes,
and 18 articles devoted exclusively to the comparative analysis
of these
parties.1 Taking into account articles devoted to individual
successor
parties or to the place of CSPs in party systems substantially
adds to
this total. No other type of party—liberal, agrarian, nationalist,
or even
extremist—has received comparable study.
7Coalition Formation in Eastern Europe
Why have these parties attracted so much attention? In the first
place, it came as a surprise to many scholars that these parties
survived
and, in some cases, transformed themselves. It was assumed that
parties
so closely associated with a repressive dictatorship would
quickly fall
by the wayside when faced with genuine competition.2
Moreover, it seemed unlikely that these parties would be able to
change their ways, given the heavy baggage that they carried
from the
past. Scholars expected these parties to remain as authoritarian
and
ideologically extreme as they had always been. For this reason,
the
ability of CSPs to win elections, first in Lithuania and Poland
and later in
other countries, led many observers to worry about a possible
reversion to
nondemocratic politics. When the election of these parties did
not
portend a return to communism, scholars wanted to know how
some
of these parties were able to transform themselves into
democratic parties.
Finally, students of postcommunist politics were interested in
how citizens and politicians would react to these parties. CSPs
were
intimately connected with some of the most repressive regimes
in
human history. Would citizens be able to forgive and forget
after the
fall of communism? Or would they hold grudges against these
parties
for the destruction their predecessors had inflicted? How
important,
in short, were legacies of the past?
A survey of the literature devoted to these parties finds that it is
focused almost entirely on party development.3 Virtually all of
this
work addresses the same two questions: (1) What explains the
success
of CSPs, either in merely surviving or in winning elections? and
(2) What explains a CSP’s ability or inability to transform into
a normal
democratic party? Most of this literature can thus be classed as
addressing the causes of these parties rather than their effects.
Instead of revisiting this research, we ask a different, and in
some
sense, more-consequential question: do CSPs matter politically?
Research has not yet shown that these parties have had a
definite effect
on politics in the region. Did it matter that CSPs managed to
survive
or transform themselves in the countries of Eastern Europe? Did
they
actually affect the substance of politics in the region? In
essence, ours
is the “so what?” question. We focus specifically on the
dynamics of
government formation and portfolio allocation. These areas are
particularly good for tests of these questions because they have
bred a
large literature (giving us a baseline of comparison) and they
are readily
quantifiable.
We believe that these questions are significant not only because
their answers may provide a validation of previous work, but
also
because they have important consequences for governance in the
region.
8 James N. Druckman and Andrew Roberts
Government formation and the allocation of portfolios have
been shown
in numerous studies to shape policy outcomes and general well -
being
(see, for example, Klingemann, Hofferbert, and Budge 1994 and
Lijphart 1999). Thus, if CSPs alter the dynamics of coalition
politics,
then this influence could ultimately have profound effects on
the politics
of the region.
II. CSPs and Coalition Theory
Just as studies on Eastern European politics have paid scant
attention to how CSPs affect coalition governance, the literature
on
coalition behavior has given limited consideration to governing
dynamics in Eastern Europe, instead focusing largely on
Western
Europe (see, however, Blondel and Müller-Rommel 2001;
Druckman
and Roberts 2005, N.d., and Grzymala-Busse 2001). That said,
coalition
theory, more generally, provides reasons to expect CSPs to
matter.
Over the last 20 years, researchers have shown how various
external constraints affect coalition behavior (see, for example,
De
Winter 1995; Druckman and Thies 2002; Huber 1996; Laver and
Schofield 1990, 195–215; Martin and Stevenson 2001, 35–38;
and
Mershon 1996). Most of these constraints come from
institutions and
include such things as formation rules (for instance, investiture
rules),
cabinet operation rules (such as votes of no confidence),
legislative
rules (such as dissolution rules), and party rules.
Most relevant for us, given our interest in CSPs, is the impact
of
party rules. Strøm, Budge, and Laver (1994) explain that
Party leaders may declare that they will, or will not, form
particular coalitions. . . .
The systematic exclusion of certain parties from coalition
bargaining is the most
striking party constraint found with any regularity. . . . The
examples of the
Gaullists or Communists in the French Fourth Republic, Sinn
Féin in Ireland, or
the Italian Communists in the 1950s show that certain parties,
as a consequence
of their strong “antisystem” stance, can effectively be
discounted as members of
any potential government. (317)
CSPs in Eastern Europe differ from these parties insofar as they
have
generally not been systematically excluded from government
formation
(Strøm, Budge, and Laver focus on Western Europe; also see
Martin
and Stevenson 2001, 37, 46; and Mershon 1994, 57; 2002, 40–
41). Yet
the basic idea that specific types of parties can alter the
dynamics of
coalition bargaining extends to the case of CSPs. Indeed, Strøm,
Budge,
and Laver (1994, 317) even acknowledge that “Besides
antisystem
parties [with whom other parties refuse to bargain], taboos are
often
9Coalition Formation in Eastern Europe
attached to parties associated with the previous political
regimes,
especially undemocratic ones.” These types of parties impose
incentives
“that change the calculus of the decision maker” (Laver and
Schofield
1990, 202).
In the case of CSPs, constraints come from the internal party
politics and party electorates of the nonsuccessor parties (see
Strøm
1990a). That is, party activists and voters of the other parties
may
oppose coalitions with CSPs for affective reasons unrelated to
party
strength and ideology. Party leaders will heed these preferences
because, in addition to pursuing office and policy, they pursue
votes
and need to maintain support from activists and voters.
The underlying reason for these attitudes is what a considerable
literature has referred to as the “regime divide”—the affective
dislike
of former opponents of communism for those associated in any
way
with the communist system (Kitschelt et al. 1999).4 The
brutality of
the communist regime is said to have led victims of the regime
to
visceral distaste for representatives of that regime. In societies
flat-
tened by communism—and thus lacking many of the political
cleavages
found in established democracies—the division between
supporters
and opponents of the old regime appears to be one of the
strongest
political cleavages. Just as the Civil War generated lasting
political
cleavages in the United States, the trauma of 40 years of
communism
should leave a lasting imprint on postcommunist politics.
This emotional distaste may be so great that it overwhelms the
desire of some CSPs to draw a thick line between themselves
and the
previous ruling parties and to present themselves as normal
players in
the democratic game.5 For many citizens, and even politicians,
the
mere thought of a CSP provokes a negative emotional reaction.
We
should add that such a reaction is not usually in response to the
current
ideology of the party—several of these parties have quite
moderate
ideologies—or to its legislative strength—none of these parties
dominates politics in the way that the former rulers did.
We believe there are two ways in which the regime divide might
affect coalition politics.6 First, it is possible that party elites
affectively
dislike CSPs so intensely that the elites sacrifice some of the
benefits
of office and policy in order to punish CSPs. This dislike may
reflect
instrumental consequences generated by intraparty politics.
Strøm,
Budge, and Laver (1994, 318) explain that “senior politicians
interact
with activists in their own parties. Party leaders may believe
that some
coalitions would be sufficiently detrimental to their recruitment
of
candidates or activists to be avoided under all circumstances. Or
they
may believe that the benefits of a potential coalition would be
10 James N. Druckman and Andrew Roberts
outweighed by the costs their own activists would impose in
irate
retaliation. . . . [T]hese risks may induce party leaders to refrain
from
otherwise attractive coalitions [for example, with CSPs].”
Second, and perhaps more important, the regime divide may
work
through the general electorate. In addition to seeking office and
policy
outcomes, parties also seek to maximize the votes they receive
in
present and future elections (Strøm 1990a). If party electorates
are
sufficiently opposed to coalitions with CSPs for the affective
reasons
we mentioned, then party elites will likely follow the
electorates’ lead.
Elites will avoid such coalitions or find ways to distance
themselves
from CSPs or keep CSPs in check within such coalitions. All of
these
strategies are motivated by a desire to avoid losing votes in
future
elections.7
As evidence of this vote-seeking motivation, Grzymala-Busse
(2001) has shown that parties that form coalitions with CSPs are
punished more strongly at the polls than parties that do not.
Anecdotal
evidence supports this view as well. Consider the active
movement in
the Czech Republic, spanning from left to right, called “One
Doesn’t
Speak with Communists” or the recent mobilizations of the
Hungarian
Fidesz party and the Polish Law and Justice Party (PiS) against
the
vestiges of communism embodied in quite liberal CSPs. The
fact that
parties in many states of the region campaign on the
anticommunism
and anti-CSP issue even today, 15 years after the transition,
indicates
that the issue must still touch a nerve with voters.8
III. Hypotheses
Given this logic, we expect that the presence of CSPs and this
regime divide will affect at least three areas of coalition
formation.
The first is participation in government. While CSPs surely
desire to
participate in government, it is possible that they are rarely
invited to
join governments. This exclusion could occur because of some
combination of affective dislike, intraparty consequences,
and/or fear
of electoral consequences. Theories of the regime divide would
thus
predict that CSPs are less likely to serve in government, all
other things
being equal. The same conclusion could flow from a
consideration of
the CSPs themselves. If they are so rigid because of their
authoritarian
past that they are unable to compromise with other parties, then
they
will be less likely to participate in coalition governments.
It is important to consider the ceteris paribus clause here. Are
CSPs less likely to serve in government, all else being equal?
The
11Coalition Formation in Eastern Europe
important control variable is party ideology. CSPs may be
discrimi-
nated against because they are extremists, that is, because they
have
not broken ties with the past and renounced the politics of the
old
regime. A number of theories of government formation argue
that
ideology matters for government participation (for instance,
Laver
1998). We wished to determine if the mere fact of being a CSP
leads to
decreased participation regardless of ideology. Does the CSP
variable
add any explanatory power above and beyond ideology? Are
these
parties excluded from power merely for being who they are? We
discuss
our test of this hypothesis in Section V.
The second possible effect of the regime divide is on cabinet
types. If there is intense affective dislike for CSPs, then they
might
only enter government as part of surplus majority coalitions.
This is
for two reasons. First, oversized coalitions help other parties to
distance
themselves from the former communists in the eyes of voters
and thus
minimize electoral punishment. Second, the inclusion of extra
parties
helps to moderate the possibly extreme or reactionary policy
proposals
of the CSPs and the concomitant uncertainty that a CSP may
bring to
governing (Dodd 1976; Riker 1962). The formation of an
oversized
coalition with the former communists was widely noted after the
Hungarian elections of 1994.9 We aimed to determine if this
tendency
toward oversized coalitions has more-general applicability. We
discuss
our test of this hypothesis in Section VI.
The third effect of CSPs is on the allocation of portfolios once a
coalition has formed. In Western Europe, coalition parties tend
to
receive portfolios in nearly one-to-one proportion to their seat
share,
with a slight small-party bias.10 Dislike for CSPs, however,
may lead
the successor parties to be compensated less than
proportionally, as
other parties try to put distance between themselves and the
former
communists for the benefit of their electorates or party activists.
Even
when CSPs form governments, they may have to offer their
coalition
partners excess portfolios in order to induce the other parties to
join
the government. On the other hand, the possible authoritarian
tendencies
of these parties may lead them to demand more than their
proportionate
share. We discuss our test of these hypotheses in Section VII.
One final note is that there are reasons to expect, contrary to
our
hypotheses, that CSPs are treated the same as other parties. If
other
parties care mainly about office and policy, as has been
emphasized in
many theories, then these parties have strong incentives to
negotiate
with CSPs as they would with other parties. There are likely to
be
costs to discriminating against CSPs, and parties concerned only
about
office or policy should try to avoid these costs.
12 James N. Druckman and Andrew Roberts
Our null hypothesis is thus that CSPs are not treated
anomalously
in government formation. If we cannot reject the null, then we
are left
to conclude that the party-specific history of the CSPs in
Eastern
European politics is not a significant factor in explaining
government
formation in this region. We would view a rejection of the null
as
evidence consistent with how constraints stemming from party
rules
(Strøm, Budge, and Laver 1994) in general and Eastern
European CSPs
in particular shape coalition politics.
IV. Data
We tested these hypotheses with a new dataset that includes
government formation decisions in Eastern Europe. The Eastern
European data come from nearly all coalitions in the 15 Eastern
European countries listed in Table 1, starting with the first
democrati-
cally elected government in each country and continuing
through
2002.11 This sample thus includes all of the parliamentary
democracies
in Eastern Europe for the lifetime of their existence. We
collected the
bulk of these data from Keesing’s Contemporary Archives,
although in
a few instances we drew on country-specific sources, including
data
directly from the country’s legislative archives.
For each government, we identified all parties in government,
every party with at least one seat in parliament (at the point of
govern-
ment formation), whether or not the party served in the previous
government, the seat share of the party, whether or not the party
was a
communist successor party, the party type of each party, and the
partisan
affiliation of each minister.
To determine if a party was a CSP, we followed Bozóki and
Ishiyama (2002).12 We drew the party type variable from
Armingeon
and Careja’s (2004) work. This variable labels each party as one
of 17
types specified by Lane, McKay, and Newton (1997):
communist,
postcommunist, left-socialist, socialist, pensioners, greens,
agrarian,
liberal, religious, conservative, nationalist, ultra-right, ethnic,
regional,
alliance, protest, and no-label. We labeled a small number of
parties
not included in their dataset ourselves. We used the party types
as a
proxy for ideology in the absence of more-direct measures. We
should
note that CSP is not a party type but a separate dummy variable;
for
example, some CSPs are classified as “communists,” while
others are
“socialists.” (We will discuss the details shortly.)
For most of the article, our unit of analysis is the party, since
we
are interested in explaining the inclusion of a party in
government and
the proportion of portfolios each party receives. We also use the
13Coalition Formation in Eastern Europe
TA
B
L
E
1
D
es
cr
ip
tio
n
of
E
as
te
rn
E
ur
op
ea
n
D
at
a
N
um
be
r
of
N
um
be
r
of
N
um
be
r
of
Y
ea
rs
o
f
N
um
be
r
of
N
um
be
r
of
C
ou
nt
ry
G
ov
er
nm
en
ts
Pa
rt
ie
s
in
L
eg
.a
Pa
rt
ie
s
in
G
ov
.b
Fi
rs
t a
nd
L
as
t G
ov
.
C
SP
s
in
L
eg
.
C
SP
s
in
G
ov
.
A
lb
an
ia
8
64
33
19
92
–2
00
2
13
%
(
8/
64
)
18
%
(
6/
33
)
B
ul
ga
ri
a
4
22
12
19
90
–2
00
1
18
%
(
4/
22
)
33
%
(
4/
12
)
C
ro
at
ia
2
30
11
20
00
–2
00
1
7%
(
2/
30
)
18
%
(
2/
11
)
C
ze
ch
os
lo
va
ki
a
2
17
5
19
90
–1
99
2
12
%
(
2/
17
)
0%
(
0/
5)
C
ze
ch
R
ep
ub
lic
3
19
9
19
93
–2
00
2
11
%
(
2/
19
)
0%
(
0/
9)
E
st
on
ia
6
46
15
19
92
–2
00
2
0%
(
0/
46
)
0%
(
0/
15
)
H
un
ga
ry
5
39
14
19
90
–2
00
2
13
%
(
5/
39
)
14
%
(
2/
14
)
L
at
vi
a
9
70
35
19
93
–2
00
0
9%
(
6/
70
)
0%
(
0/
35
)
L
it
hu
an
ia
5
28
12
19
96
–2
00
1
11
%
(
3/
28
)
0%
(
0/
12
)
M
ac
ed
on
ia
4
30
13
19
94
–2
00
0
13
%
(
4/
30
)
15
%
(
2/
13
)
Po
la
nd
9
94
32
19
89
–2
00
1
10
%
(
9/
94
)
16
%
(
5/
32
)
R
om
an
ia
9
63
31
19
91
–2
00
0
14
%
(
9/
63
)
19
%
(
6/
31
)
Se
rb
ia
1
8
2
19
98
13
%
(
1/
8)
50
%
(
1/
2)
Sl
ov
ak
ia
4
25
14
19
93
–1
99
8
8%
(
2/
25
)
14
%
(
2/
14
)
Sl
ov
en
ia
5
38
18
19
93
–2
00
0
13
%
(
5/
38
)
11
%
(
2/
18
)
A
ll
C
ou
nt
ri
es
76
59
3
25
6
19
89
–2
00
2
11
%
(
62
/5
93
)
13
%
(
32
/2
56
)
a I
nc
lu
de
s
an
y
pa
rt
y
w
ith
a
t l
ea
st
o
ne
le
gi
sl
at
ur
e
se
at
, o
ve
r t
he
c
as
es
o
f a
ll
go
ve
rn
m
en
ts
fo
rm
ed
. T
he
re
w
er
e
76
to
ta
l g
ov
er
nm
en
ts
th
at
in
cl
ud
ed
a
to
ta
l o
f 2
56
pa
rt
ie
s
ou
t o
f
a
to
ta
l o
f
59
3
pa
rt
ie
s
in
th
e
le
gi
sl
at
ur
es
.
b S
ev
en
p
ar
tie
s
en
te
re
d
a
go
ve
rn
m
en
t d
es
pi
te
h
av
in
g
no
le
gi
sl
at
iv
e
se
at
s:
f
ou
r
pa
rt
ie
s
in
a
s
in
gl
e
A
lb
an
ia
n
go
ve
rn
m
en
t,
on
e
pa
rt
y
in
tw
o
B
ul
ga
ri
an
g
ov
er
n-
m
en
ts
, a
nd
o
ne
p
ar
ty
i
n
on
e
H
un
ga
ri
an
g
ov
er
nm
en
t.
14 James N. Druckman and Andrew Roberts
coalition as our unit when we consider the influence of CSPs on
cabinet
types. In total, there are 76 coalition governments, 593 parties
in the
legislature, and 256 parties in government. In Table 1, we
report, for
each Eastern European country, the number of governments, the
number
of parties in the legislature and government, the years of the
first and
most recent governments, and the frequency of CSPs in the
legislature
and in government.
V. Government Participation
Are CSPs discriminated against in government formation? Table
1
gives an indication of the prevalence of CSPs in Eastern
Europe. Of
the 593 parties that received legislative sets in our dataset, 62
(11%)
were CSPs. As far as government participation goes, CSPs
constituted
32 of 256 parties (13%) in government. On the surface there
does not
appear to be discrimination, but these results do not control for
party
size and ideology.
Table 2 is a cross-tabulation of CSP and party type. As
mentioned,
CSPs come from various different types (that is, party type
reflects
ideology, whereas CSP status reflects historical origin). The
table shows
that CSPs fall into five different party types: communist,
postcommunist, left-socialist, socialist, and ethnic. Note that
CSPs make
up only 31% (62/202) of these five party types (the other 69%
of these
party types are not CSPs). This distinction will later allow us to
control
for ideology. There are other parties that share the same
ideological
space but do not carry the historical baggage of the CSPs.
To determine the causes of government participation, we would,
ideally, examine the factors that lead to the creation of different
coalitions. This analysis would require specifying all of the
possible
coalitions that might form and then measuring all factors that
might
affect formation, including ideology and institutional variables
(Martin
and Stevenson 2001).
We did not have access to all of these variables, and thus we
conducted a more-exploratory analysis to determine if there is
any
basis for believing that CSPs are treated differently than other
parties.
Our dependent variable in these regressions is whether or not a
party
participated in government. Because our dependent variable is
dichoto-
mous, we used logit regressions in all of the analyses that
follow.
We identified a number of independent variables that might
affect
government participation. First, conventional theories of size
predict
that larger parties are more likely to participate in government
(Martin
and Stevenson 2001). To account for this possibility, one of our
15Coalition Formation in Eastern Europe
TABLE 2
CSP Legislative Parties
Party Typea Not CSP CSP Total
Communist 1 (number) 8 9
11% (row %) 89% 100%
1% (column %) 13% 5%
Postcommunist 2 18 20
10% 90% 100%
1% 29% 10%
Left-socialist 14 1 15
93% 7% 100%
10% 2% 7%
Socialist 72 33 105
69% 31% 100%
51% 53% 52%
Ethnic 51 2 53
96% 4% 100%
36% 3% 26%
Total 140 62 202
69% 31% 100%
100% 100% 100%
aTable includes only the parties belonging to the 5 listed party
types. Not included
are the following other party types, comprising 391 parties:
Pensioners, Green,
Agrarian, Liberal, Religious, Conservative, Nationalist,
Ultraright, Regional, Alliance,
Protest, Non-Label/others, for a total of 17 types (and 593
legislative parties).
Source: Armingeon and Careja 2004.
independent variables is the seat share of each party in
parliament.13 A
second variable that might affect participation is incumbency
(Martin
and Stevenson 2001; Strøm, Budge, and Laver 1994). Parties
that have
served in the previous government are more likely to serve in
the current
government; they are part of the status quo.
Finally, we included a measure of party ideology. Most theories
of government formation postulate that parties are at least
partially
motivated by policy. Parties thus judge the suitability of
coalition
partners by their policy stances. As a result, a party’s ideology
will
help to determine whether or not it enters government. Our
measure of
ideology is less precise than those of other studies, which use
expert
16 James N. Druckman and Andrew Roberts
judgments or analyses of party manifestos to pinpoint specific
ideological locations; such measures are not yet publicly
available for
Eastern Europe. We therefore sought to capture ideology with
Armingeon and Careja’s (2004) coding of party types for all
political
parties in Eastern Europe. As previously noted, this measure
classifies
all parties in Eastern Europe into one of 17 party types, and
each CSP
is classified into one of these party types. Because CSP itself is
not a
party type, when we added party type controls we were able to
control
for the ideology of CSPs (see Table 2).
We ran all analysis with and without the incumbency variable,
because including incumbency reduces the size of the data
(from 593
to 475 parties), since the initial governments are excluded.
Fortunately,
the results are virtually identical, regardless of whether or not
we
include incumbency; thus, in Table 3, we only present the
results that
include incumbency (since it is itself significant). We therefore
report
results with 475 cases rather than 593. We report one-tailed
tests
because we clearly predicted a negative relationship between
CSP,
our key variable, and government participation.
Model 1 tests whether or not seat share and incumbency states
predict participation in government. The results for both
variables are
highly significant and in the correct direction. Larger parties
and
incumbents are more likely to participate in government. In
Model 2, we
introduced the variable in which we are interested theoretically.
The
communist successor party variable is highly significant,
substantively
large, and, as expected, has a negative sign. CSPs are far less
likely to
serve in governments than are other parties with the same seat
share.
We next introduced controls for ideology, aiming to determine
if
the penalty for being a CSP is due to the party’s ideology or to
the
mere fact of being a CSP. In Model 3, we added dummy
variables for
all five party types of the CSPs (communist, postcommunist,
left-
socialist, socialist, and ethnic). The results indicate that the
CSP penalty
is robust to the addition of these ideological controls: the CSP
variable
emerges as both negative and significant, while four of the five
dummies
are insignificant (postcommunists are marginally
advantaged).14
To get a sense of the substantive impact of the CSP effect, we
conducted a simulation using Clarify (Tomz, Wittenberg, and
King
1999). Setting all other variables at their means, we found that
being a
CSP reduces a party’s chances of serving in government on
average by
19% (from 42% to 23%).15 This appears to us to be a quite
substantial
effect. In sum, we have found that communist successor parties
are
less likely than other parties to participate in government, even
when
we control for size, incumbency, and ideology.
17Coalition Formation in Eastern Europe
TABLE 3
Determinants of Government Participation
Dependent Variable: Whether or not a given party participated
in government
(1 = participated, 0 = did not participate)
Model
Independent Variable (1) (2) (3)
Legislative seat share 5.95** 6.57** 6.76***
(.99) (1.06) (1.1)
Incumbencya 1.37** 1.35** 1.34***
(.22) (.22) (.22)
CSP –0.70* –1.08**
(.41) (.52)
Communist party 0.085
(1.2)
Postcommunist party 1.11
(.86)
Left-socialist party –0.52
(.67)
Socialist party 0.26
(.31)
Ethnic party –0.25
(.38)
Constant –1.56** –1.56** –1.63***
(.17) (.17) (.20)
Log-likelihood –268.4 –267.1 –265.6
Observations 475 475 475
aThe number of cases reduces to 475 because we exclude all
first governments in
which there were no incumbents. Results are robust if we
instead include all first
governments without the incumbency variable.
Note: Entries are logit coefficients, with standard errors in
parentheses.
***p ≤ .01; **p ≤ .05; *p ≤ .1, one-tailed tests.
VI. Cabinet Types
Although CSPs are discriminated against in government forma-
tion, some CSPs do ultimately enter cabinets. In this section, we
address
the question of what these cabinets look like: what sort of
cabinets do
CSPs enter? Most theories of government formation predict the
formation of some form of minimal winning coalition, but there
have
18 James N. Druckman and Andrew Roberts
been several attempts to account for minority and oversized
coalitions
(see Martin and Stevenson 2001; Strøm 1990b; and Volden and
Carrubba 2004). What these theories explicitly do not
hypothesize is
that certain parties will tend to join one type of coalition more
than
others.
We argue, however, that the desire of most democratic parties
to
distance themselves from communist successor parties might
lead them
to be part of distinctive coalitions. In particular, CSPs should
more
commonly end up in oversized coalitions. Oversized coalitions
would
serve two purposes for non-CSPs. First, they would help protect
non-
CSPs’ reputations. Accountability is harder in large coalitions
because
of the difficulty in pinpointing responsibility. Parties that have
to enter
coalitions with the former communists might demand to add
extra
parties, so as not to look like they are too close to the CSPs.
Second,
extra parties would help to restrain the communists and promote
consensus in policymaking (and also lessen the uncertainty
involved
with predicting CSP behavior; see Dodd 1976 and Riker 1962).
The
more parties that are included in the coalition, the less influence
the
communists will have, since voting in the council of ministers
typically
gives each minister one vote.
Our data confirm this expectation. Table 4 shows the percentage
of cabinet types including and not including CSPs.16 A full
78% (25/
32) of governments with CSPs are oversized, compared to only
43%
(19/44) of governments without CSPs (z = 3.05; p < .01 for one-
tailed
difference-of-proportions test). While minimal winning
coalitions and
minority coalitions are common—constituting 56.5% (9/44 are
minority and 16/44 are minimal winning) of the total—in
governments
without CSPs, they are quite rare—only 21.5% (3/32 are
minority and
4/32 are minimal winning)—in governments that include a CSP.
These results raise an intriguing question: if coalitions add
surplus
parties to protect themselves against CSPs, then why do they
include
CSPs in the first place? We have some preliminary evidence
that
suggests that, in most cases, governing parties include CSPs
because
it is necessary if the parties hope to maintain a governing
majority. We
show this necessity by exploring the rate at which CSPs in
govern-
ment are pivotal. A party is pivotal when its removal changes a
majority
coalition to a minority coalition (Schofield and Laver 1985).
We found
that 69% (22/32) of the CSPs in government are pivotal,
compared to
only 39% (87/224) of non-CSPs in government (z = 3.21; p <
.01 for
two-tailed difference-of-proportions test). Moreover, nearly all
of the
ten nonpivotal CSPs in government belonged to exceptional
coalitions:
three of them belonged to minority coalitions in which no party
was
19Coalition Formation in Eastern Europe
TABLE 4
Cabinet Types in Eastern Europe
Cabinet Type No CSPs in Government A CSP in Government
Total
Minority 20.5% (9) 9.0% (3) 16% (12)
Minimal Winning 36.0% (16) 12.5% (4) 26% (20)
Oversized 43.0% (19) 78.0% (25) 58% (44)
Total 100% (44) 100% (32) 100% (76)
pivotal by definition, and six of them belonged to near-unity
coalitions.
In the latter cases, parties controlled approximately 91% of the
legis-
lative seats, meaning that, to be pivotal, a particular party
would have
to be composed of a near majority itself.17
In short, we find that CSPs are usually included in governments
because they are necessary for a majority. Of course, one may
question
the desirability of having a majority when a minority without a
CSP is
sustainable (see, for example, Strøm 1990b). But there are good
reasons
why parties might prefer to join majority coalitions in transition
countries. Majorities should help coalitions to pass legislation.
In times
of major reforms, and particularly reforms with enormous
distribu-
tional consequences, parties would like the security of having a
reliable
majority in parliament. Also, parliamentary voting in new
democracies
tends to be unstable, and parties may not be able to discipline
their
members (Andrews 2002). There is also a high rate of party
switching
among members of parliament (Kreuzer and Pettai 2003; Shabad
and
Slomczynski 2004). This switching makes majorities even more
important, and we suspect it enables CSPs to enter
governments—
governments which, in turn, try to protect themselves from
CSPs by
forming oversized coalitions that dilute the visibility and
influence of
the former communists.18
VII. Ministerial Allocation
We now turn to our third dependent variable. The way that port-
folios are allocated to parties in a governing coalition has been
closely
studied in Western Europe. This research has revealed one of
the stron-
gest relations in political science. Gamson’s Law postulates that
each
coalition party receives portfolios in direct proportion to the
percentage
20 James N. Druckman and Andrew Roberts
of seats that it contributes to the coalition (see Gamson
1961).19 For
example, a party with 30% of the seats in a coalition receives
about
30% of the portfolios.
It is not clear if Gamson’s Law is a universal law, applying in
all
contexts, or is specific to the circumstances of Western Europe.
One
possible challenge to the law comes from communist successor
parties
in Eastern Europe. If these parties behave differently or are
treated
differently than other parties, then this bias might show up in
the process
of portfolio allocation.
Indeed, the regime divide theory argues that rival parties harbor
negative feelings toward CSPs. This ill will may result in CSPs
being
undercompensated relative to proportionality. Other parties may
be
reluctant to grant CSPs their fair share of ministries. In turn,
CSPs
may be willing to sacrifice some of their fair share in order to
be allowed
into governments. On the other hand—and contrary to the
general
regime-divide theoretical framework—if CSPs maintain their
authori-
tarian ways from communism, then they might be expected to
demand
more than their fair share of portfolios. Winner-take-all norms
were
common under communism and might be expected to persist,
particu-
larly for successor parties. In this case, we would expect CSPs
to receive
more than their fair share of portfolios.
To test these possibilities, our dependent variable is the
percentage
of portfolios allocated to the party in question. Previous work
has
identified two independent variables that affect the percentage
of port-
folios that a party receives. One is the percentage of legislative
seats
that a party contributes to the coalition (a la Gamson’s Law;
see, for
example, Browne and Franklin 1973). We refer to this variable
as seat
share. The other variable is whether or not a party is a
formateur. There
remains controversy, however, about whether formateurs tend to
be
under- or overcompensated (see Ansolabehere et al. 2005;
Baron and
Ferejohn 1989; Harrington 1990; Morelli 1999; and Warwick
and
Druckman 2001, 2006). We add to these variables a new
variable indi-
cating whether or not a party is a communist successor party.
This is
the variable we are interested in theoretically.20
Following Warwick and Druckman (2001), we ran OLS regres-
sions without an intercept, although the results are robust to
alternative
specifications, such as including an intercept. Because we left
out the
intercept, we did not include main-effect dummy variables, as
this step
would have been akin to including an intercept. Thus, both the
formateur variable and the CSP variable are interacted with the
seat
share variable. If the CSP interaction term is significant, then
this result
indicates that CSPs are allocated portfolios nonproportionally.
21Coalition Formation in Eastern Europe
TABLE 5
Portfolio Allocation in Eastern Europe
(standard errors in parentheses)
Dependent Variable: Party’s share of portfolios
Model
Independent Variable (4) (5) (6)
Seat contribution 0.94*** 0.92*** 0.94***
(.02) (.04) (.04)
Formateur status x Seat contribution 0.03 0.08*
(.04) (.05)
CSP x Seat contribution –0.17***
(0.04)
Observations 256 256 256
Note: Entries are OLS unstandardized slope coefficients, with
intercepts set equal to 0.
***p ≤ .01; **p ≤ .05; * p ≤ .1, two-tailed tests.
Table 5 presents our regression results.21 (We report two-tailed
significance tests because of our dueling hypotheses about the
CSP
effect.) In Model 4, we included only the seat share variable.
The
variable is highly significant and nearly proportional (beta =
0.94).
Model 5 included the formateur interaction term. This variable
is
insignificant, indicating that formateurs are neither under- nor
over-
compensated relative to their seat shares. The seat share
variable
remains significant and substantively almost identical.
We next included the CSP interaction variable. Model 6 shows
that this variable is both highly significant and substantively
important.
The negative sign on the variable indicates that CSPs receive
less than
their proportional share of portfolios. The effect is also
substantively
important. Communist successor parties receive approximately
17%
less than their fair share of portfolios. We also see in this
regression
that, once we control for CSP status, formateurs receive a slight
bonus.
Thus, non-CSP formateurs take more than their share. This
pattern
differs from that found in Western Europe, a distinction we
have
explored in other work (see Druckman and Roberts 2005).
In short, CSPs are penalized in portfolio allocation. The fact
that
they are penalized lends itself to an important interpretation. At
the
outset of this section, we suggested two possible outcomes to
alloca-
tion: If CSPs act like their predecessors, then they will demand
over-
compensation. If they are the object of other parties’ disdain,
then CSPs
22 James N. Druckman and Andrew Roberts
will be undercompensated. Our finding of undercompensation
indicates
that the decisive factor is not the CSPs themselves but the
attitude of
other parties toward them.
VIII. Time and Space
These results convince us that CSPs elicit distinctive coalition
dynamics in Eastern Europe, but there may also be variations
across
time or space. First, our theory is based on the affective dislike
of
voters and elites toward the former communists. It is likely that
these
emotions will diminish over time as memories fade and the
former
communists become accepted players in the democratic game.
To probe
this possibility, we reran our analyses, cutting our sample at its
midpoint
of 1996. We found that the two time periods looked very
similar. All of
the aspects of CSP discrimination we uncovered in the previous
analyses
appear both before and after 1996. (We experimented with
various other
time splits, and in no instance did we find a significant time
effect.)
While this result strikes us as surprising, it does correspond
with
qualitative observations of the region. In three of the most
recent
elections in the region (in Poland, Hungary, and the Czech
Republic),
a key—perhaps the dominant—element in the campaigns of
right-wing
parties was an evocation of the dangers or injustice of letting
CSPs
rule. The regime divide appears to have considerable power to
structure
politics even 15 years after the transition.
Eastern Europe also features considerable variation over space.
As Kitschelt et al. (1999) note, Eastern Europe exhibits
considerably
more spatial diversity than other regions in the world. Indeed,
many
analyses have divided the region into more-advanced and less-
advanced
halves (King 2000; Vachudova and Snyder 1997). By “more
advanced,”
we mean countries widely considered to have attained standards
of
democracy and development close to those of the established
democ-
racies of Western Europe. By contrast, “less-advanced”
countries have
significant shortcomings in the functioning of both democracy
and the
economy. The more-advanced countries entered the European
Union
(EU) in May 2004, they have been more democratic as measured
by
Freedom House, and they have higher incomes and higher
scores on
the World Bank’s Human Development Index. The less-
advanced coun-
tries did not enter the EU and have significantly lower ratings
on the
other measures.
For the purposes of our analyses, the key fact would be whether
or not attitudes toward the former communists differ between
these
two groups of countries. We do not have direct evidence on this
point,22
23Coalition Formation in Eastern Europe
but we have some reason to believe that there are differences.
More-
advanced countries have a considerably larger middl e class,
which
sees communism as having limited its opportunities to attain
Western
standards of living. These individuals are thus more likely to
hold a
grudge against the CSPs and punish cooperation with them. In
less-
advanced countries, by contrast, the middle class is much
smaller, and
there is a much larger lower class whose position has worsened
since
the end of communism. As a result, there should be greater
acceptance
of the representatives of the old regime.
It is possible, of course, that we may witness the opposite
effects.
In less-advanced countries, the communist regime was typically
more
repressive than in the more-advanced ones. As a result, it is
possible
that CSPs will be viewed more negatively in less-advanced
countries
and discrimination will be more extreme there.
To test these ideas, we divided the sample into two groups. The
main variable we used to distinguish them was their average
Freedom
House score during the 1990s. Our advanced countries included
Czechoslovakia, the Czech Republic, Estonia, Hungary, Latvia,
Lithuania, Poland, and Slovenia; our non-advanced countries
included
Albania, Bulgaria, Croatia, Macedonia, Romania, Serbia, and
Slovakia.
This division also corresponds to the first wave of accession to
the
EU, with the exception of Slovakia, which is classed as less
advanced
(the results are robust to classifying Slovakia as more
advanced).
To determine if CSPs are treated differently when it comes to
government formation in the two groups of countries, we added
two
variables to Table 3, Model 3: a dummy variable distinguishing
between
more-advanced and less-advanced countries, and an interaction
between
this more-advanced/less-advanced variable and the CSP
variable. The
interaction is marginally significant (p ≤ .15).
It is thus possible that the regime divide is stronger in the more-
advanced countries. Citizens of these countries might view the
old
regime as having impeded their development and thus wish to
punish
the successors to these parties. Citizens of less-advanced
countries are
less likely to harbor negative affect toward communism and
thus are
less likely to penalize parties associated with the old regime.
We
emphasize, however, that this supposition is quite speculative,
given
the marginal significance of the result. Also, when we turn to
cabinet
types and portfolio allocation, we find no significant differences
across
regions. Cabinets with CSPs have a higher likelihood of being
over-
sized than those that do not include CSPs, in both less-advanced
and
more-advanced countries, and portfolio allocation in both types
of
countries awards less than a proportional number of portfolios
to CSPs.23
24 James N. Druckman and Andrew Roberts
IX. Conclusion
Although scholars of parliamentary government have often
recognized that the identity of individual parties matters for
coalition
formation, this fact has not often been included in quantitative
studies.
Preference has been given to the more analytically tractable
concepts
of legislative strength and ideology.
The experience of Eastern European countries provides an inter-
esting example of how party identity may matter for coalition
formation.
These countries have recently emerged from dictatorships that
have
left important scars on the polity. These scars remain fresh
because
representatives of the old regime continue to contest elections
in the
new regime. There are thus good reasons to believe that other
parties,
and particularly their electorates, will view communist
successor parties
not only in terms of their legislative strength and ideology, but
also in
terms of their identity as representatives of the old regime.
In this article, we have shown that this bias emerges in three
facets of government formation. Communist successor parties
are less
likely to enter government than other parties, and when they do
enter
government, they tend to be part of oversized coalitions and to
be
allocated less than their proportional share of portfolios. CSPs
do suffer
discrimination at the hands of other parties purely for what they
are.
While we do not have direct evidence on why CSPs suffer from
discrimination, these results appear to be consistent with
theories of
the regime divide in the region. The most plausible explanation
is that
the electorates of parties associated with the opposition to
commu-
nism still hold affective dislike for their former oppressors and
wish to
penalize them. Parties will presumably heed these preferences,
because
they would lose votes by doing otherwise.
The implication is that scholars researching other new democra-
cies may want to pay more attention to the coalition preferences
of
voters. It is in these countries that the affective feelings of
voters toward
particular parties are likely to be the strongest, and parties thus
face
considerable pressure to attend to these preferences.
This research validates both the suggestion of coalition theorists
that party identity may matter in coalition formation and the
idea that
vote-seeking plays an important role in parties’ decisions about
coalitions. Neither idea is new, but both have been neglected in
the
quantitative study of coalition politics. Our results suggest that
scholars
should pay more attention to affective dislike between
supporters of rival
parties and the consequences this bias has for parties that, in
addition to
seeking office and policy outcomes, worry about their future
electability.
25Coalition Formation in Eastern Europe
We believe two extensions of this research to be especially
compelling (in addition to the aforementioned need to analyze
coalition
formation using Martin and Stevenson’s approach). First,
scholars
might ask if CSPs affect other facets of coalition government,
such as
government duration and, most important, policy choices.
Studies of
Western Europe suggest that the composition of governments
does
affect policy, but this influence has yet to be shown in Eastern
Europe.
The second extension would be to investigate whether or not
these
legacies of the old regime matter in other new democracies. Are
repre-
sentatives of the old regime penalized more generally, or are
our results
specific to the postcommunist world?
James N. Druckman ([email protected]) is Associate
Professor of Political Science and Andrew Roberts
([email protected]) is Assistant Professor of Political
Science, both at Northwestern University, 601 University Place,
Evanston, IL 60208.
NOTES
We thank Michael Parkin for research assistance and Lanny
Martin and the
reviewers for helpful comments. Druckman acknowledges
support from the University
of Minnesota McKnight Land-Grant Professorship and from
Northwestern University’s
AT&T Research Scholar Funds.
1. Among the comparative works on the topic are Bozóki and
Ishiyama 2002;
Curry and Urban 2003; Evans and Whitefield 1995; Grzymala-
Busse 1998, 2001, 2002a;
Ishiyama 1995, 1996, 1997, 1998, 1999a, 1999b; Ishiyama and
Bozóki 2001; Mahr
and Nagle 1995; Moraski and Loewenberg 1999; Orenstein
1998; Waller 1995; and
Ziblatt 1998. Many more articles focusing on individual CSPs
could be cited.
2. This expectation is frequently exaggerated. Even the most
repressive dicta-
torships serve some constituency that might be expected to
continue its support after a
democratic transition.
3. Exceptions include Bunce 2002; Grzymala-Busse 2001,
2002b; and Ishiyama
1999c. In fact, Grzymala-Busse’s (2001) article considers the
same issue as this article—
the effect of the communist legacy on coalition formation. Our
article extends her
work by taking a large-N approach, allowing the inclusion of
control variables, and
looking at additional aspects of coalition formation.
4. Kitschelt et al. (1999, 65) define the regime divide as the
phenomenon wherein
“memories about old-regime performance, periodically updated
by more recent events,
affect people’s orientation toward the pre-democratic
incumbents.” Grzymala-Busse
(2001, 85) calls it “the depth and character of the persisting
conflict between the
successors to the pre-1989 Communist parties and the parties
emerging from the
Communist-era opposition.”
5. All of the successor parties considered here have proclaimed,
rhetorically at
least, support for the democratic process.
26 James N. Druckman and Andrew Roberts
6. Grzymala-Busse (2001) suggests an additional way, the
desire of parties to
build reputations. While we agree with this outlook, we believe
that this desire works
through the vote-seeking motivation that we emphasize, as
Grzymala-Busse herself
seems to suggest.
7. We would add the possibility that CSPs elicit distinctive
dynamics because
they behave differently than other parties, perhaps by retaining
their authoritarian
ways. We later discuss this possibility in more detail, but we do
not find any confir-
mation of it. It is worth noting that this expectation generates
predictions that are the
opposite of those suggested by the regime divide theory.
8. There are additional reasons why vote seeking might be
particularly
important in Eastern Europe. First, voters have punished
incumbents quite heavily in
the region. Vote losses in the double digits are the norm rather
than the exception for
sitting governments (Roberts 2006). Further, parties appear and
disappear with great
frequency in the region (Rose and Munro 2003). A single poor
election result is often
enough to push a party into oblivion. Parties thus have good
reason to weigh care-
fully the possibility of offending their electorates, even if they
are tempted by the
spoils of office and policy influence.
9. The Hungarian Socialist Party won 54% of the seats in this
election and
yet still entered a coalition with the second-place party, the
Alliance of Free Democrats.
10. As we will discuss later, there is an active debate about
whether formateurs
are advantaged or disadvantaged in portfolio allocation (see
Warwick and Druckman
2006).
11. We excluded caretaker governments, technocratic
(nonpartisan) govern-
ments, and single-party governments. We also included only
those governments that
passed an investiture vote (if one was held). A government ends
and another one
begins when an election occurs, the head of government
changes, the party member-
ship of the government changes, or the government resigns
(Warwick and Druckman
2001, 633). Data details are available from the authors.
12. Following all other work on the topic, we did not count the
puppet allies of
the communist party, such as the Polish Peasants’ Party.
Citizens surely realized that
these parties did not exercise any power, and thus the parties
should not have been
blamed for the regime’s crimes.
13. Martin and Stevenson (2001) have found that it is not size
per se that
affects entry into government but rather formateur status.
Parties that are formateurs
are more likely to enter government. Because all of the
formateurs in our dataset
entered government (that is, we coded only successful
formateurs, for the purposes
of portfolio allocation), we cannot test this possibility here.
Since, however, size is
related to formateur status—larger parties are more likely to be
formateurs—this
omission should not bias our results. Indeed, in our dataset, the
average seat share of
formateurs is 37% compared to 11% for nonformateurs.
14. We conducted several robustness checks on these results.
First, since our
data include different numbers of coalitions in each country
(e.g., one in Serbia, nine
in Poland), some countries may influence the results more than
others. We thus reran
our regressions using country weights, and we found no
substantive difference from
the results reported in Table 3. Second, participation by the
same parties in the same
coalition-formation episode is not independent. We thus ran
specifications that used
clustering on the formation episode and robust standard errors.
Again, we found no
27Coalition Formation in Eastern Europe
difference in results using this specification. Third, we added
dummies for parties on
the far right—nationalist and ultra-rightist parties. Again, the
CSP variable remains
highly significant, although we did find that nationalists are
penalized as well.
Strangely, ultra-rightist parties are not treated differently.
Finally, we included an
interaction term between CSP and seat share, as the impact of
CSP status may depend
on seat share. The interaction term is marginally significant at
first (as CSPs grow
larger, they are advantaged relative to other parties), but the
significant effect disappears
when we control for incumbency. The main effect of CSPs
remains, despite these
controls.
15. Details, including standard errors, are available from the
authors.
16. There are no cases of multiple CSPs in governme nt. We also
conducted
regression analyses that control for the number of parties in the
coalition, the number
of parties in the legislature, and the types of parties in the
coalition. Even with the
inclusion of these controls, the presence of a CSP still makes a
coalition significantly
more likely to be oversized.
17. The one exception was the first Slovenian government,
which was neither
a minority nor a near-unity coalition, although it did control
68% of the legislative
seats. We also note that, among majority governments, 46.5%
(87/187) of non-CSPs
were pivotal, compared to 75% (22/29) of CSPs (z = 2.86, p <
.01 for a two-tailed
difference-of-proportions test).
18. Note two other points. First, CSPs are not more likely to be
pivot parties
when we control for party size. This result is of limited interest,
however, because it
simply reveals the tautology that larger parties are more likely
than smaller parties to
be pivotal. The fact is that when such larger parties are CSPs,
they are included,
presumably because of their pivotal status. In other cases, CSPs
tend not be included,
whereas other parties are. Second, we found that, in many cases,
a CSP in govern-
ment is the only pivotal party. Among majority coalitions, only
13% (11/87) of non-
CSPs are the single pivotal party in a coalition. The analogous
figure for CSPs is
59% (13/22).
19. There is typically some deviation from proportionality in
the form of a
small-party bias, such that small parties receive a bit more than
their share and large
parties, including the formateurs, receive less (see Warwick and
Druckman 2001,
2006).
20. We did not include controls for ideology or incumbency in
this analysis.
Prior work has not considered these variables, and we do not
see any reason why
they should affect portfolio allocation. Furthermore, ideology
controls would suffer
from multicollinearity with the CSP variable, as the ideologies
of CSPs that enter
government are much more limited than the types that receive
legislative seats. When
we regress the CSP interaction on the country dummy
interactions, the R2 is .89.
21. As in the analysis of participation, we also ran regressions
with country
weights to account for the fact that some countries have more
coalitions than others.
These weights do not affect the substantive results.
22. Ideal would be comparative public opinion data on attitudes
toward CSPs
as acceptable members of government. We would be particularly
interested in the
intensity of these feelings, as that would give us an idea of
whether or not there
would be electoral punishment for forming coalitions with
CSPs. We did find data
from the New Democracies Barometer on attitudes toward the
old regime in general
28 James N. Druckman and Andrew Roberts
(Rose and Haerpfer 1996). These data indicate that advanced
countries are slightly
more likely to view the communist regime negatively, but the
differences are not
large.
23. In other work, we have found that the formateur effect
differs between the
two groups of countries; this finding does not have implications
for CSPs per se, however
(see Druckman and Roberts 2005).
REFERENCES
Andrews, Josephine. 2002. When Majorities Fail: The Russian
Parliament, 1990–
1993. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Ansolabehere, Stephen, James M. Snyder, Jr., Aaron B. Strauss,
and Michael M. Ting.
2005. “Voting Weights and Formateur Advantages in the
Formation of Coali-
tion Governments.” American Journal of Political Science 49:
550–63.
Armingeon, Klaus, and Romana Careja. 2004. Comparative Data
Set for 28 Post-
Communist Countries, 1989–2004. Bern, Switzerland: Institute
of Political
Science, University of Berne.
Baron, David, and John Ferejohn. 1989. “Bargaining in
Legislatures.” American
Political Science Review 83: 1181–1206.
Blondel, Jean, and Ferdinand Müller-Rommel, eds. 2001.
Cabinets in Eastern Europe.
New York: Palgrave.
Bozóki, András, and John T. Ishiyama, eds. 2002. The
Communist Successor Parties
of Central and Eastern Europe. Armonk, NY: M.E. Sharpe.
Browne, Eric, and Mark Franklin. 1973. “Aspects of Coalition
Payoffs in European
Parliamentary Democracies.” American Political Science
Review 67: 453–69.
Bunce, Valerie. 2002. “The Return of the Left and Democratic
Consolidation in Poland
and Hungary.” In The Communist Successor Parties of Central
and Eastern
Europe, ed. András Bozóki and John T. Ishiyama. Armonk, NY:
M.E. Sharpe.
Curry, Jane Leftwich, and Joan Urban, eds. 2003. The Left
Transformed in
Postcommunist Societies: The Cases of East-Central Europe,
Russia, and
Ukraine. Lanham, MD: Rowan and Littlefield.
De Winter, Lieven. 1995. “The Role of Parliament in
Government Formation and
Resignation.” In Parliaments and Majority Rule in Western
Europe, ed. Herbert
Doring. Frankfurt: Campus Verlag.
Dodd, Lawrence C. 1976. Coalitions in Parliamentary
Government. Princeton, NJ:
Princeton University Press.
Druckman, James N., and Andrew Roberts. 2005. “Context and
Coalition Bargaining:
Comparing Portfolio Allocation in Eastern and Western
Europe.” Party Politics
11: 535–55.
Druckman, James N., and Andrew Roberts. N.d. “Measuring
Portfolio Salience in
Eastern European Parliamentary Democracies.” European
Journal of Political
Research. Forthcoming.
Druckman, James N., and Michael F. Thies. 2002. “The
Importance of Concurrence:
The Impact of Bicameralism on Government Formation and
Duration.” American
Journal of Political Science 46: 760–71.
29Coalition Formation in Eastern Europe
Evans, Geoffrey, and Stephen Whitefield. 1995. “Economic
Ideology and Political
Success: Communist Successor Parties in the Czech Republic,
Slovakia and
Hungary Compared.” Party Politics 1: 565–78.
Gamson, William A. 1961. “A Theory of Coalition Formation.”
American Sociological
Review 26: 373–82.
Grzymala-Busse, Anna. 1998. “Reform Efforts in the Czech and
Slovak Communist
Parties and Their Successors, 1988–1993.” East European
Politics and Societies
12: 442–71.
Grzymala-Busse, Anna. 2001. “Coalition Formation and the
Regime Divide in New
Democracies: East Central Europe.” Comparative Politics 34:
85–104.
Grzymala-Busse, Anna. 2002a. Redeeming the Communist Past:
The Regeneration of
Communist Successor Parties in East Central Europe.
Cambridge: Cambridge
University Press.
Grzymala-Busse, Anna. 2002b. “The Effects of Communist
Party Transformation on
the Institutionalization of Party Systems.” In The Communist
Successor Parties
of Central and Eastern Europe, ed. András Bozóki and John T.
Ishiyama. Armonk,
NY: M.E. Sharpe.
Harrington, Joseph. 1990. “The Power of the Proposal Maker in
a Model of Endog-
enous Agenda Formation.” Public Choice 64: 1–20.
Huber, John D. 1996. “The Vote of Confidence in Parliamentary
Democracies.”
American Political Science Review 90: 269–82.
Ishiyama, John. 1995. “Communist Parties in Transition:
Structures, Leaders, and
Processes of Democratization in Eastern Europe.” Comparative
Politics 27:
147–66.
Ishiyama, John. 1996. “Red Phoenix? The Communist Party in
Post-Soviet Russian
Politics.” Party Politics 2: 147–75.
Ishiyama, John. 1997. “The Sickle or the Rose?: Previous
Regime Types and the
Evolution of the Ex-Communist Parties in Post-Communist
Politics.”
Comparative Political Studies 30: 299–330.
Ishiyama, John. 1998. “Red versus Expert: Candidate
Recruitment and Communist
Party Adaptation in Post Soviet Politics.” Party Politics 4: 297–
318.
Ishiyama, John. 1999a. “The Communist Successor Parties and
Party Organizational
Development in Post-Communist Politics.” Political Research
Quarterly 53:
87–112.
Ishiyama, John. 1999b. Communist Successor Parties in Post-
Communist Politics.
Carmack, NY: Nova Science.
Ishiyama, John. 1999c. “Sickles into Roses: The Communist
Successor Parties and Demo-
cratic Consolidation in Comparative Perspective.”
Democratization 6: 52–73.
Ishiyama, John, and András Bozóki. 2001. “Adaptation and
Change: Characterizing
the Survival Strategies of Communist Successor Parties.”
Journal of Communist
Studies and Transition Politics 17: 32–51.
Keesing’s Contemporary Archives. 1990–2003. London:
Keesing’s Publications.
King, Charles. 2000. “Post-Postcommunism: Transition,
Comparison, and the End of
Eastern Europe.” World Politics 53: 143–72.
Kitschelt, Herbert, Zdenka Mansfeldova, Radoslaw Markowski,
and Gabor Toka. 1999.
Post-Communist Party Systems: Competition, Representation,
and Inter-Party
Cooperation. New York: Cambridge University Press.
30 James N. Druckman and Andrew Roberts
Klingemann, Hans-Dieter, Richard I. Hofferbert, and Ian Budge.
1994. Parties, Policies,
and Democracy. Boulder, CO: Westview.
Kreuzer, Marcus, and Vello Pettai. 2003. “Patterns of Political
Instability: Affiliation
Patterns of Politicians and Voters in Post-Communist Estonia,
Latvia, and
Lithuania.” Studies in Comparative International Development
38: 76–98.
Lane, Jan-Erik, David McKay, and Kenneth Newton. 1997.
Political Data Handbook.
2d ed. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Laver, Michael. 1998. “Models of Government Formation.”
Annual Review of Political
Science 1: 1–25.
Laver, Michael, and Norman Schofield. 1990. Multiparty
Government: The Politics of
Coalition in Europe. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Laver, Michael, and Kenneth Shepsle. 1996. Making and
Breaking Governments. New
York: Cambridge University Press.
Lijphart, Arend. 1999. Patterns of Democracy: Majoritarian and
Consensus Forms in
36 Democracies. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.
Mahr, Allison, and John Nagle. 1995. “Resurrection of the
Successor Parties and
Democratization in East-Central Europe.” Communist and Post-
Communist
Studies 28: 393–409.
Martin, Lanny W., and Randolph T. Stevenson. 2001.
“Government Formation in
Parliamentary Democracies.” American Journal of Political
Science 45: 33–50.
Mershon, Carol. 1994. “Expectations and Informal Rules in
Coalition Formation.”
Comparative Political Studies 27: 40–79.
Mershon, Carol. 1996. “The Costs of Coalition: Coalition
Theories and Italian
Governments.” American Political Science Review 90: 534–54.
Mershon, Carol. 2002. The Costs of Coalition. Stanford, CA:
Stanford University Press.
Moraski, Bryon, and Gerhard Loewenberg. 1999. “The Effect of
Legal Thresholds on
the Revival of Former Communist Parties in East-Central
Europe.” Journal of
Politics 61: 151–70.
Morelli, Massimo. 1999. “Demand Competition and Policy
Compromise in Legisla-
tive Bargaining.” American Political Science Review 93: 809–
20.
Orenstein, Mitchell. 1998. “A Genealogy of Communist
Successor Parties in East-
Central Europe and the Determinants of their Success.” East
European Politics
and Societies 12: 472–99.
Riker, William. 1962. The Theory of Political Coalitions. New
Haven, CT: Yale
University Press.
Roberts, Andrew. 2006. “Hyperaccountability: Economic Voting
in Eastern Europe.”
Northwestern University. Typescript.
Rose, Richard, and Christian Haerpfer. 1996. “Change and
Stability in the New Democ-
racies Barometer.” University of Strathclyde: Center for the
Study of Public Policy.
Rose, Richard, and Neil Munro. 2003. Elections and Parties in
New European
Democracies. Washington, DC: CQ.
Schofield, Norman, and Michael Laver. 1985. “Bargaining
Theory and Portfolio Pay-
offs in European Coalition Governments, 1945–83.” British
Journal of Political
Science 15: 143–64.
Shabad, Goldie, and Kazimierz M. Slomczynski. 2004. “Inter -
party Mobility among
Parliamentary Candidates in Post-Communist East Central
Europe.” Party Politics
10: 151–76.
31Coalition Formation in Eastern Europe
Strøm, Kaare. 1990a. “A Behavioral Theory of Competitive
Parties.” American Journal
of Political Science 34: 565–98.
Strøm, Kaare. 1990b. Minority Government and Majority Rule.
Cambridge: Cambridge
University Press.
Strøm, Kaare, Ian Budge, and Michael Laver. 1994.
“Constraints on Government
Formation in Parliamentary Democracies.” American Journal of
Political Sci-
ence 38: 303–35.
Tomz, Michael, Jason Wittenberg, and Gary King. 1999.
“Clarify.” Version 1.2.1
http://gking.harvard.edu (June 1, 1999).
Vachudova, Milada Anna, and Tim Snyder. 1997. “Are
Transitions Transitory? Two
Types of Political Change in Eastern Europe since 1989.” East
European Politics
and Societies 11: 1–35.
Volden, Craig, and Clifford J. Carrubba. 2004. “The Formation
of Oversized Coali-
tions in Parliamentary Democracies.” American Journal of
Political Science
48: 521–37.
Waller, Michael. 1995. “Adaptation of the Former Communist
Parties of East-Central
Europe. A Case of Democratization?” Party Politics 1: 373–90.
Warwick, Paul V., and James N. Druckman. 2001. “Portfolio
Salience and the Propor-
tionality of Payoffs in Coalition Governments.” British Journal
of Political
Science 31: 627–49.
Warwick, Paul V., and James N. Druckman. 2006. “The Paradox
of Portfolio Alloca-
tion: An Investigation into the Nature of a Very Strong but
Puzzling Relation-
ship.” European Journal of Political Research 45: 635–65.
Ziblatt, Daniel F. 1998. “The Adaptation of Ex-Communist
Parties to Post-Communist
East Central Europe: A Comparative Study of the East German
and Hungarian
Ex-Communist Parties.” Communist and Post Communist
Studies 31: 119–37.
32 James N. Druckman and Andrew Roberts
<<
/ASCII85EncodePages false
/AllowTransparency false
/AutoPositionEPSFiles true
/AutoRotatePages /None
/Binding /Left
/CalGrayProfile (Gray Gamma 2.2)
/CalRGBProfile (Adobe RGB 0501998051)
/CalCMYKProfile (U.S. Web Coated 050SWOP051 v2)
/sRGBProfile (sRGB IEC61966-2.1)
/CannotEmbedFontPolicy /Error
/CompatibilityLevel 1.3
/CompressObjects /Off
/CompressPages true
/ConvertImagesToIndexed true
/PassThroughJPEGImages true
/CreateJDFFile false
/CreateJobTicket false
/DefaultRenderingIntent /Default
/DetectBlends true
/DetectCurves 0.1000
/ColorConversionStrategy /LeaveColorUnchanged
/DoThumbnails false
/EmbedAllFonts true
/EmbedOpenType false
/ParseICCProfilesInComments true
/EmbedJobOptions true
/DSCReportingLevel 0
/EmitDSCWarnings false
/EndPage -1
/ImageMemory 1048576
/LockDistillerParams true
/MaxSubsetPct 100
/Optimize true
/OPM 1
/ParseDSCComments true
/ParseDSCCommentsForDocInfo true
/PreserveCopyPage false
/PreserveDICMYKValues true
/PreserveEPSInfo true
/PreserveFlatness false
/PreserveHalftoneInfo false
/PreserveOPIComments false
/PreserveOverprintSettings true
/StartPage 1
/SubsetFonts false
/TransferFunctionInfo /Apply
/UCRandBGInfo /Remove
/UsePrologue false
/ColorSettingsFile (Color Management Off)
/AlwaysEmbed [ true
/Courier
/Courier-Bold
/Courier-BoldOblique
/Courier-Oblique
/Helvetica
/Helvetica-Bold
/Helvetica-BoldOblique
/Helvetica-Oblique
/Symbol
/Times-Bold
/Times-BoldItalic
/Times-Italic
/Times-Roman
/ZapfDingbats
]
/NeverEmbed [ true
]
/AntiAliasColorImages false
/CropColorImages false
/ColorImageMinResolution 266
/ColorImageMinResolutionPolicy /Warning
/DownsampleColorImages false
/ColorImageDownsampleType /None
/ColorImageResolution 300
/ColorImageDepth -1
/ColorImageMinDownsampleDepth 1
/ColorImageDownsampleThreshold 1.50000
/EncodeColorImages true
/ColorImageFilter /DCTEncode
/AutoFilterColorImages true
/ColorImageAutoFilterStrategy /JPEG
/ColorACSImageDict <<
/QFactor 0.15
/HSamples [1 1 1 1] /VSamples [1 1 1 1]
>>
/ColorImageDict <<
/QFactor 0.15
/HSamples [1 1 1 1] /VSamples [1 1 1 1]
>>
/JPEG2000ColorACSImageDict <<
/TileWidth 256
/TileHeight 256
/Quality 30
>>
/JPEG2000ColorImageDict <<
/TileWidth 256
/TileHeight 256
/Quality 30
>>
/AntiAliasGrayImages false
/CropGrayImages false
/GrayImageMinResolution 266
/GrayImageMinResolutionPolicy /Warning
/DownsampleGrayImages false
/GrayImageDownsampleType /None
/GrayImageResolution 300
/GrayImageDepth -1
/GrayImageMinDownsampleDepth 2
/GrayImageDownsampleThreshold 1.50000
/EncodeGrayImages true
/GrayImageFilter /DCTEncode
/AutoFilterGrayImages true
/GrayImageAutoFilterStrategy /JPEG
/GrayACSImageDict <<
/QFactor 0.15
/HSamples [1 1 1 1] /VSamples [1 1 1 1]
>>
/GrayImageDict <<
/QFactor 0.15
/HSamples [1 1 1 1] /VSamples [1 1 1 1]
>>
/JPEG2000GrayACSImageDict <<
/TileWidth 256
/TileHeight 256
/Quality 30
>>
/JPEG2000GrayImageDict <<
/TileWidth 256
/TileHeight 256
/Quality 30
>>
/AntiAliasMonoImages false
/CropMonoImages false
/MonoImageMinResolution 900
/MonoImageMinResolutionPolicy /Warning
/DownsampleMonoImages false
/MonoImageDownsampleType /None
/MonoImageResolution 1200
/MonoImageDepth -1
/MonoImageDownsampleThreshold 1.50000
/EncodeMonoImages true
/MonoImageFilter /CCITTFaxEncode
/MonoImageDict <<
/K -1
>>
/AllowPSXObjects false
/CheckCompliance [
/None
]
/PDFX1aCheck false
/PDFX3Check false
/PDFXCompliantPDFOnly false
/PDFXNoTrimBoxError true
/PDFXTrimBoxToMediaBoxOffset [
0.00000
0.00000
0.00000
0.00000
]
/PDFXSetBleedBoxToMediaBox true
/PDFXBleedBoxToTrimBoxOffset [
0.00000
0.00000
0.00000
0.00000
]
/PDFXOutputIntentProfile (None)
/PDFXOutputConditionIdentifier ()
/PDFXOutputCondition ()
/PDFXRegistryName ()
/PDFXTrapped /False
/Description <<
/CHS
<FEFF4f7f75288fd94e9b8bbe5b9a521b5efa76840020005000440
04600206587686353ef901a8fc7684c976262535370673a548c002
000700072006f006f00660065007200208fdb884c9ad88d2891cf6
2535370300260a853ef4ee54f7f75280020004100630072006f006
2006100740020548c002000410064006f00620065002000520065
006100640065007200200035002e003000204ee553ca66f49ad87
248672c676562535f00521b5efa76840020005000440046002065
8768633002>
/CHT
<FEFF4f7f752890194e9b8a2d7f6e5efa7acb76840020004100640
06f006200650020005000440046002065874ef653ef5728684c976
2537088686a5f548c002000700072006f006f00660065007200204
e0a73725f979ad854c18cea7684521753706548679c300260a853e
f4ee54f7f75280020004100630072006f0062006100740020548c0
02000410064006f00620065002000520065006100640065007200
200035002e003000204ee553ca66f49ad87248672c4f86958b555f
5df25efa7acb76840020005000440046002065874ef63002>
/DAN
<FEFF004200720075006700200069006e0064007300740069006
c006c0069006e006700650072006e0065002000740069006c0020
006100740020006f0070007200650074007400650020004100640
06f006200650020005000440046002d0064006f006b0075006d00
65006e007400650072002000740069006c0020006b00760061006
c00690074006500740073007500640073006b007200690076006e
0069006e006700200065006c006c006500720020006b006f00720
0720065006b007400750072006c00e60073006e0069006e006700
2e0020004400650020006f0070007200650074007400650064006
50020005000440046002d0064006f006b0075006d0065006e0074
006500720020006b0061006e002000e50062006e0065007300200
0690020004100630072006f00620061007400200065006c006c00
6500720020004100630072006f006200610074002000520065006
100640065007200200035002e00300020006f00670020006e0079
006500720065002e>
/DEU
<FEFF00560065007200770065006e00640065006e00200053006
90065002000640069006500730065002000450069006e00730074
0065006c006c0075006e00670065006e0020007a0075006d00200
0450072007300740065006c006c0065006e00200076006f006e00
2000410064006f006200650020005000440046002d0044006f006
b0075006d0065006e00740065006e002c00200076006f006e0020
00640065006e0065006e002000530069006500200068006f00630
06800770065007200740069006700650020004400720075006300
6b006500200061007500660020004400650073006b0074006f007
0002d0044007200750063006b00650072006e00200075006e0064
002000500072006f006f0066002d00470065007200e4007400650
06e002000650072007a0065007500670065006e0020006d00f600
63006800740065006e002e002000450072007300740065006c006
c007400650020005000440046002d0044006f006b0075006d0065
006e007400650020006b00f6006e006e0065006e0020006d00690
0740020004100630072006f00620061007400200075006e006400
2000410064006f006200650020005200650061006400650072002
00035002e00300020006f0064006500720020006800f600680065
007200200067006500f600660066006e006500740020007700650
07200640065006e002e>
/ESP
<FEFF005500740069006c0069006300650020006500730074006
100200063006f006e0066006900670075007200610063006900f3
006e0020007000610072006100200063007200650061007200200
064006f00630075006d0065006e0074006f007300200064006500
2000410064006f006200650020005000440046002000700061007
2006100200063006f006e00730065006700750069007200200069
006d0070007200650073006900f3006e002000640065002000630
061006c006900640061006400200065006e00200069006d007000
7200650073006f007200610073002000640065002000650073006
3007200690074006f00720069006f002000790020006800650072
00720061006d00690065006e00740061007300200064006500200
063006f00720072006500630063006900f3006e002e0020005300
65002000700075006500640065006e00200061006200720069007
200200064006f00630075006d0065006e0074006f007300200050
00440046002000630072006500610064006f007300200063006f0
06e0020004100630072006f006200610074002c00200041006400
6f00620065002000520065006100640065007200200035002e003
000200079002000760065007200730069006f006e006500730020
0070006f00730074006500720069006f007200650073002e>
/FRA
<FEFF005500740069006c006900730065007a002000630065007
30020006f007000740069006f006e00730020006100660069006e
00200064006500200063007200e90065007200200064006500730
0200064006f00630075006d0065006e0074007300200041006400
6f00620065002000500044004600200070006f007500720020006
400650073002000e9007000720065007500760065007300200065
0074002000640065007300200069006d007000720065007300730
069006f006e007300200064006500200068006100750074006500
20007100750061006c0069007400e900200073007500720020006
40065007300200069006d007000720069006d0061006e00740065
00730020006400650020006200750072006500610075002e00200
04c0065007300200064006f00630075006d0065006e0074007300
2000500044004600200063007200e900e90073002000700065007
500760065006e0074002000ea0074007200650020006f00750076
0065007200740073002000640061006e007300200041006300720
06f006200610074002c002000610069006e007300690020007100
75002700410064006f00620065002000520065006100640065007
200200035002e0030002000650074002000760065007200730069
006f006e007300200075006c007400e9007200690065007500720
0650073002e>
/ITA
<FEFF005500740069006c0069007a007a0061007200650020007
10075006500730074006500200069006d0070006f007300740061
007a0069006f006e0069002000700065007200200063007200650
0610072006500200064006f00630075006d0065006e0074006900
2000410064006f006200650020005000440046002000700065007
200200075006e00610020007300740061006d0070006100200064
00690020007100750061006c0069007400e000200073007500200
07300740061006d00700061006e00740069002000650020007000
72006f006f0066006500720020006400650073006b0074006f007
0002e0020004900200064006f00630075006d0065006e00740069
00200050004400460020006300720065006100740069002000700
06f00730073006f006e006f0020006500730073006500720065002
000610070006500720074006900200063006f006e002000410063
0072006f00620061007400200065002000410064006f006200650
02000520065006100640065007200200035002e00300020006500
2000760065007200730069006f006e00690020007300750063006
3006500730073006900760065002e>
/JPN
<FEFF9ad854c18cea51fa529b7528002000410064006f00620065
00200050004400460020658766f8306e4f5c6210306b4f7f752830
57307e30593002537052376642306e753b8cea309267005927965
0306b4fdd306430533068304c3067304d307e3059300230c730b9
30af30c830c330d730d730ea30f330bf3067306e53705237307e30
5f306f30d730eb30fc30d57528306b9069305730663044307e3059
30023053306e8a2d5b9a30674f5c62103055308c305f0020005000
440046002030d530a130a430eb306f3001004100630072006f006
2006100740020304a30883073002000410064006f006200650020
00520065006100640065007200200035002e003000204ee5964d3
067958b304f30533068304c3067304d307e30593002>
/KOR
<FEFFc7740020c124c815c7440020c0acc6a9d558c5ec0020b370
c2a4d06cd0d10020d504b9b0d1300020bc0f0020ad50c815ae30c5
d0c11c0020ace0d488c9c8b85c0020c778c1c4d560002000410064
006f0062006500200050004400460020bb38c11cb97c0020c791c
131d569b2c8b2e4002e0020c774b807ac8c0020c791c131b41c002
00050004400460020bb38c11cb2940020004100630072006f0062
006100740020bc0f002000410064006f006200650020005200650
06100640065007200200035002e00300020c774c0c1c5d0c11c00
20c5f40020c2180020c788c2b5b2c8b2e4002e>
/NLD (Gebruik deze instellingen om Adobe PDF-documenten
te maken voor kwaliteitsafdrukken op desktopprinters en
proofers. De gemaakte PDF-documenten kunnen worden
geopend met Acrobat en Adobe Reader 5.0 en hoger.)
/NOR
<FEFF004200720075006b0020006400690073007300650020006
9006e006e007300740069006c006c0069006e00670065006e0065
002000740069006c002000e50020006f007000700072006500740
0740065002000410064006f006200650020005000440046002d00
64006f006b0075006d0065006e00740065007200200066006f007
20020007500740073006b00720069006600740020006100760020
006800f800790020006b00760061006c006900740065007400200
07000e500200062006f007200640073006b007200690076006500
7200200065006c006c00650072002000700072006f006f0066006
50072002e0020005000440046002d0064006f006b0075006d0065
006e00740065006e00650020006b0061006e002000e50070006e0
0650073002000690020004100630072006f006200610074002000
65006c006c00650072002000410064006f0062006500200052006
5006100640065007200200035002e003000200065006c006c0065
0072002000730065006e006500720065002e>
/PTB
<FEFF005500740069006c0069007a00650020006500730073006
1007300200063006f006e00660069006700750072006100e700f5
0065007300200064006500200066006f0072006d0061002000610
0200063007200690061007200200064006f00630075006d006500
6e0074006f0073002000410064006f00620065002000500044004
60020007000610072006100200069006d00700072006500730073
00f5006500730020006400650020007100750061006c006900640
0610064006500200065006d00200069006d007000720065007300
73006f0072006100730020006400650073006b0074006f0070002
0006500200064006900730070006f00730069007400690076006f
0073002000640065002000700072006f00760061002e0020004f0
07300200064006f00630075006d0065006e0074006f0073002000
5000440046002000630072006900610064006f007300200070006
f00640065006d0020007300650072002000610062006500720074
006f007300200063006f006d0020006f0020004100630072006f00
6200610074002000650020006f002000410064006f00620065002
000520065006100640065007200200035002e0030002000650020
007600650072007300f50065007300200070006f0073007400650
0720069006f007200650073002e>
/SUO
<FEFF004b00e40079007400e40020006e00e40069007400e4002
000610073006500740075006b007300690061002c0020006b0075
006e0020006c0075006f0074002000410064006f0062006500200
050004400460020002d0064006f006b0075006d0065006e007400
740065006a00610020006c0061006100640075006b00610073007
4006100200074007900f6007000f60079007400e400740075006c
006f0073007400750073007400610020006a00610020007600650
064006f0073007400750073007400610020007600610072007400
65006e002e00200020004c0075006f00640075007400200050004
40046002d0064006f006b0075006d0065006e0074006900740020
0076006f0069006400610061006e0020006100760061007400610
020004100630072006f0062006100740069006c006c0061002000
6a0061002000410064006f0062006500200052006500610064006
5007200200035002e0030003a006c006c00610020006a00610020
0075007500640065006d006d0069006c006c0061002e>
/SVE
<FEFF0041006e007600e4006e00640020006400650020006800e
4007200200069006e0073007400e4006c006c006e0069006e0067
00610072006e00610020006f006d0020006400750020007600690
06c006c00200073006b006100700061002000410064006f006200
650020005000440046002d0064006f006b0075006d0065006e007
40020006600f600720020006b00760061006c0069007400650074
0073007500740073006b007200690066007400650072002000700
0e5002000760061006e006c00690067006100200073006b007200
6900760061007200650020006f006300680020006600f60072002
0006b006f007200720065006b007400750072002e002000200053
006b006100700061006400650020005000440046002d0064006f0
06b0075006d0065006e00740020006b0061006e002000f6007000
70006e00610073002000690020004100630072006f00620061007
40020006f00630068002000410064006f00620065002000520065
006100640065007200200035002e00300020006f0063006800200
0730065006e006100720065002e>
/ENU (Use these settings to create Adobe PDF documents for
quality printing on desktop printers and proofers. Created PDF
documents can be opened with Acrobat and Adobe Reader 5.0
and later.)
>>
/Namespace [
(Adobe)
(Common)
(1.0)
]
/OtherNamespaces [
<<
/AsReaderSpreads false
/CropImagesToFrames false
/ErrorControl /WarnAndContinue
/FlattenerIgnoreSpreadOverrides true
/IncludeGuidesGrids false
/IncludeNonPrinting false
/IncludeSlug false
/Namespace [
(Adobe)
(InDesign)
(4.0)
]
/OmitPlacedBitmaps false
/OmitPlacedEPS false
/OmitPlacedPDF false
/SimulateOverprint /Legacy
>>
<<
/AddBleedMarks false
/AddColorBars false
/AddCropMarks true
/AddPageInfo false
/AddRegMarks false
/BleedOffset [
9
9
9
9
]
/ConvertColors /NoConversion
/DestinationProfileName ()
/DestinationProfileSelector /NA
/Downsample16BitImages true
/FlattenerPreset <<
/ClipComplexRegions true
/ConvertStrokesToOutlines false
/ConvertTextToOutlines false
/GradientResolution 300
/LineArtTextResolution 1200
/PresetName ([High Resolution])
/PresetSelector /HighResolution
/RasterVectorBalance 1
>>
/FormElements false
/GenerateStructure false
/IncludeBookmarks false
/IncludeHyperlinks false
/IncludeInteractive false
/IncludeLayers false
/IncludeProfiles false
/MarksOffset 12
/MarksWeight 0.125000
/MultimediaHandling /UseObjectSettings
/Namespace [
(Adobe)
(CreativeSuite)
(2.0)
]
/PDFXOutputIntentProfileSelector /NA
/PageMarksFile /RomanDefault
/PreserveEditing true
/UntaggedCMYKHandling /LeaveUntagged
/UntaggedRGBHandling /LeaveUntagged
/UseDocumentBleed false
>>
<<
/AllowImageBreaks true
/AllowTableBreaks true
/ExpandPage false
/HonorBaseURL true
/HonorRolloverEffect false
/IgnoreHTMLPageBreaks false
/IncludeHeaderFooter false
/MarginOffset [
0
0
0
0
]
/MetadataAuthor ()
/MetadataKeywords ()
/MetadataSubject ()
/MetadataTitle ()
/MetricPageSize [
0
0
]
/MetricUnit /inch
/MobileCompatible 0
/Namespace [
(Adobe)
(GoLive)
(8.0)
]
/OpenZoomToHTMLFontSize false
/PageOrientation /Portrait
/RemoveBackground false
/ShrinkContent true
/TreatColorsAs /MainMonitorColors
/UseEmbeddedProfiles false
/UseHTMLTitleAsMetadata true
>>
]
>> setdistillerparams
<<
/HWResolution [2400 2400]
/PageSize [612.000 792.000]
>> setpagedevice
Counseling Disposition Reflection Worksheet
Directions: Review the dispositions document and select three
dispositions that you currently meet. Complete the chart by
listing the dispositions met as well as a description of how you
meet the disposition. Include a citation and paraphrase the
definition. Please note: you do not need to be actively
practicing to complete this worksheet.
Disposition and Definition
Description of how the disposition is met (75-100 words)
1.
2.
3.
Directions: Now that you have identified dispositions that you
currently meet, review the disposition document again and
consider any dispositions that you do not meet. Complete the
chart below by adding the two dispositions you do not meet as
well as a preliminary plan in regards to how you plan to
improve the identified dispositions.
Disposition and Definition
Description of how you plan to improve the disposition
(75-100 words)
1.
2.
© 2016. Grand Canyon University. All Rights Reserved.
© 2014. Grand Canyon University. All Rights Reserved.

More Related Content

Similar to Counseling Disposition Reflection WorksheetDirections

Political Behavior, Vol. 15, No. 4, 1993 .docx
Political Behavior, Vol. 15, No. 4, 1993        .docxPolitical Behavior, Vol. 15, No. 4, 1993        .docx
Political Behavior, Vol. 15, No. 4, 1993 .docxLacieKlineeb
 
Oligarchy rules democracy: Testing Theories of American Politics: Elites, Int...
Oligarchy rules democracy: Testing Theories of American Politics: Elites, Int...Oligarchy rules democracy: Testing Theories of American Politics: Elites, Int...
Oligarchy rules democracy: Testing Theories of American Politics: Elites, Int...Sadanand Patwardhan
 
CHAPTER 1Incorporating Political Indicatorsinto Comparat.docx
CHAPTER 1Incorporating Political Indicatorsinto Comparat.docxCHAPTER 1Incorporating Political Indicatorsinto Comparat.docx
CHAPTER 1Incorporating Political Indicatorsinto Comparat.docxwalterl4
 
1. Public Policy Understanding public policy is both an art a.docx
1. Public Policy Understanding public policy is both an art a.docx1. Public Policy Understanding public policy is both an art a.docx
1. Public Policy Understanding public policy is both an art a.docxjackiewalcutt
 
Power and interdependence
Power and interdependencePower and interdependence
Power and interdependencewaqarunisa
 
Political Science Semester 1 (102).pdf11
Political Science Semester 1 (102).pdf11Political Science Semester 1 (102).pdf11
Political Science Semester 1 (102).pdf11osmandhux
 
approaches to policy making.pdf
approaches to policy making.pdfapproaches to policy making.pdf
approaches to policy making.pdfJohnRichCaidic
 
Approaches to the study of Public Policy.pdf
Approaches to the study of Public Policy.pdfApproaches to the study of Public Policy.pdf
Approaches to the study of Public Policy.pdfWAQARULLAHZIA1
 
EmailPhoneView AuditPrincipal InvestigatorEmai.docx
EmailPhoneView AuditPrincipal InvestigatorEmai.docxEmailPhoneView AuditPrincipal InvestigatorEmai.docx
EmailPhoneView AuditPrincipal InvestigatorEmai.docxSALU18
 
Unit 1 Comparative methods and Approaches
Unit 1 Comparative methods and ApproachesUnit 1 Comparative methods and Approaches
Unit 1 Comparative methods and ApproachesYash Agarwal
 
Public Policy and Public Opinion
Public Policy and Public OpinionPublic Policy and Public Opinion
Public Policy and Public OpinionJacqueline Faerman
 
Americanpoliticalsystemppt 110919181530-phpapp01
Americanpoliticalsystemppt 110919181530-phpapp01Americanpoliticalsystemppt 110919181530-phpapp01
Americanpoliticalsystemppt 110919181530-phpapp01Wayne Williams
 
Comparative political system
Comparative political systemComparative political system
Comparative political systemYash Agarwal
 
Public Opinion and Public Policy.docx
Public Opinion and Public Policy.docxPublic Opinion and Public Policy.docx
Public Opinion and Public Policy.docxLaxmikant Paudel
 
IMPACT OF COALITION POLITICS ON FEDERAL INSTITUTIONS -THE INDIAN EXPERIENCE
IMPACT OF COALITION POLITICS ON FEDERAL INSTITUTIONS -THE INDIAN EXPERIENCEIMPACT OF COALITION POLITICS ON FEDERAL INSTITUTIONS -THE INDIAN EXPERIENCE
IMPACT OF COALITION POLITICS ON FEDERAL INSTITUTIONS -THE INDIAN EXPERIENCEAngela Williams
 
Businessman Candidates.pdf
Businessman Candidates.pdfBusinessman Candidates.pdf
Businessman Candidates.pdfJhon Mejer Purba
 
CP 501 LECTURE ONE political science annavvsnsnvbshbsbbbshnsbhshjsjvshhsjsjbs...
CP 501 LECTURE ONE political science annavvsnsnvbshbsbbbshnsbhshjsjvshhsjsjbs...CP 501 LECTURE ONE political science annavvsnsnvbshbsbbbshnsbhshjsjvshhsjsjbs...
CP 501 LECTURE ONE political science annavvsnsnvbshbsbbbshnsbhshjsjvshhsjsjbs...DishuSingh8
 

Similar to Counseling Disposition Reflection WorksheetDirections (20)

Political Behavior, Vol. 15, No. 4, 1993 .docx
Political Behavior, Vol. 15, No. 4, 1993        .docxPolitical Behavior, Vol. 15, No. 4, 1993        .docx
Political Behavior, Vol. 15, No. 4, 1993 .docx
 
Oligarchy rules democracy: Testing Theories of American Politics: Elites, Int...
Oligarchy rules democracy: Testing Theories of American Politics: Elites, Int...Oligarchy rules democracy: Testing Theories of American Politics: Elites, Int...
Oligarchy rules democracy: Testing Theories of American Politics: Elites, Int...
 
CHAPTER 1Incorporating Political Indicatorsinto Comparat.docx
CHAPTER 1Incorporating Political Indicatorsinto Comparat.docxCHAPTER 1Incorporating Political Indicatorsinto Comparat.docx
CHAPTER 1Incorporating Political Indicatorsinto Comparat.docx
 
1. Public Policy Understanding public policy is both an art a.docx
1. Public Policy Understanding public policy is both an art a.docx1. Public Policy Understanding public policy is both an art a.docx
1. Public Policy Understanding public policy is both an art a.docx
 
C4 - Levels of Analysis
C4 - Levels of AnalysisC4 - Levels of Analysis
C4 - Levels of Analysis
 
Power and interdependence
Power and interdependencePower and interdependence
Power and interdependence
 
Political Science Semester 1 (102).pdf11
Political Science Semester 1 (102).pdf11Political Science Semester 1 (102).pdf11
Political Science Semester 1 (102).pdf11
 
approaches to policy making.pdf
approaches to policy making.pdfapproaches to policy making.pdf
approaches to policy making.pdf
 
Approaches to the study of Public Policy.pdf
Approaches to the study of Public Policy.pdfApproaches to the study of Public Policy.pdf
Approaches to the study of Public Policy.pdf
 
EmailPhoneView AuditPrincipal InvestigatorEmai.docx
EmailPhoneView AuditPrincipal InvestigatorEmai.docxEmailPhoneView AuditPrincipal InvestigatorEmai.docx
EmailPhoneView AuditPrincipal InvestigatorEmai.docx
 
Unit 1 Comparative methods and Approaches
Unit 1 Comparative methods and ApproachesUnit 1 Comparative methods and Approaches
Unit 1 Comparative methods and Approaches
 
Public Policy and Public Opinion
Public Policy and Public OpinionPublic Policy and Public Opinion
Public Policy and Public Opinion
 
co.pol
co.polco.pol
co.pol
 
Americanpoliticalsystemppt 110919181530-phpapp01
Americanpoliticalsystemppt 110919181530-phpapp01Americanpoliticalsystemppt 110919181530-phpapp01
Americanpoliticalsystemppt 110919181530-phpapp01
 
Comparative political system
Comparative political systemComparative political system
Comparative political system
 
Public Opinion and Public Policy.docx
Public Opinion and Public Policy.docxPublic Opinion and Public Policy.docx
Public Opinion and Public Policy.docx
 
IMPACT OF COALITION POLITICS ON FEDERAL INSTITUTIONS -THE INDIAN EXPERIENCE
IMPACT OF COALITION POLITICS ON FEDERAL INSTITUTIONS -THE INDIAN EXPERIENCEIMPACT OF COALITION POLITICS ON FEDERAL INSTITUTIONS -THE INDIAN EXPERIENCE
IMPACT OF COALITION POLITICS ON FEDERAL INSTITUTIONS -THE INDIAN EXPERIENCE
 
SociologyExchange.co.uk Shared Resource
SociologyExchange.co.uk Shared ResourceSociologyExchange.co.uk Shared Resource
SociologyExchange.co.uk Shared Resource
 
Businessman Candidates.pdf
Businessman Candidates.pdfBusinessman Candidates.pdf
Businessman Candidates.pdf
 
CP 501 LECTURE ONE political science annavvsnsnvbshbsbbbshnsbhshjsjvshhsjsjbs...
CP 501 LECTURE ONE political science annavvsnsnvbshbsbbbshnsbhshjsjvshhsjsjbs...CP 501 LECTURE ONE political science annavvsnsnvbshbsbbbshnsbhshjsjvshhsjsjbs...
CP 501 LECTURE ONE political science annavvsnsnvbshbsbbbshnsbhshjsjvshhsjsjbs...
 

More from CruzIbarra161

Business and Government Relations  Please respond to the following.docx
Business and Government Relations  Please respond to the following.docxBusiness and Government Relations  Please respond to the following.docx
Business and Government Relations  Please respond to the following.docxCruzIbarra161
 
Business Continuity Planning Explain how components of the busine.docx
Business Continuity Planning Explain how components of the busine.docxBusiness Continuity Planning Explain how components of the busine.docx
Business Continuity Planning Explain how components of the busine.docxCruzIbarra161
 
business and its environment Discuss the genesis, contributing fac.docx
business and its environment Discuss the genesis, contributing fac.docxbusiness and its environment Discuss the genesis, contributing fac.docx
business and its environment Discuss the genesis, contributing fac.docxCruzIbarra161
 
business and its environment Discuss the genesis, contributing facto.docx
business and its environment Discuss the genesis, contributing facto.docxbusiness and its environment Discuss the genesis, contributing facto.docx
business and its environment Discuss the genesis, contributing facto.docxCruzIbarra161
 
Business BUS 210 research outline1.Cover page 2.Table .docx
Business BUS 210 research outline1.Cover page 2.Table .docxBusiness BUS 210 research outline1.Cover page 2.Table .docx
Business BUS 210 research outline1.Cover page 2.Table .docxCruzIbarra161
 
BUS 439 International Human Resource ManagementInstructor Steven .docx
BUS 439 International Human Resource ManagementInstructor Steven .docxBUS 439 International Human Resource ManagementInstructor Steven .docx
BUS 439 International Human Resource ManagementInstructor Steven .docxCruzIbarra161
 
BUS 439 International Human Resource ManagementEmployee Value Pr.docx
BUS 439 International Human Resource ManagementEmployee Value Pr.docxBUS 439 International Human Resource ManagementEmployee Value Pr.docx
BUS 439 International Human Resource ManagementEmployee Value Pr.docxCruzIbarra161
 
Bullzeye is a discount retailer offering a wide range of products,.docx
Bullzeye is a discount retailer offering a wide range of products,.docxBullzeye is a discount retailer offering a wide range of products,.docx
Bullzeye is a discount retailer offering a wide range of products,.docxCruzIbarra161
 
Building on the work that you prepared for Milestones One through Th.docx
Building on the work that you prepared for Milestones One through Th.docxBuilding on the work that you prepared for Milestones One through Th.docx
Building on the work that you prepared for Milestones One through Th.docxCruzIbarra161
 
Budget Legislation Once the budget has been prepared by the vari.docx
Budget Legislation Once the budget has been prepared by the vari.docxBudget Legislation Once the budget has been prepared by the vari.docx
Budget Legislation Once the budget has been prepared by the vari.docxCruzIbarra161
 
Browsing the podcasts on iTunes or YouTube, listen to a few of Gramm.docx
Browsing the podcasts on iTunes or YouTube, listen to a few of Gramm.docxBrowsing the podcasts on iTunes or YouTube, listen to a few of Gramm.docx
Browsing the podcasts on iTunes or YouTube, listen to a few of Gramm.docxCruzIbarra161
 
Brown Primary Care Dental clinics Oral Health Initiative p.docx
Brown Primary Care Dental clinics Oral Health Initiative p.docxBrown Primary Care Dental clinics Oral Health Initiative p.docx
Brown Primary Care Dental clinics Oral Health Initiative p.docxCruzIbarra161
 
BUDDHISMWEEK 3Cosmogony - Origin of the UniverseNature of .docx
BUDDHISMWEEK 3Cosmogony - Origin of the UniverseNature of .docxBUDDHISMWEEK 3Cosmogony - Origin of the UniverseNature of .docx
BUDDHISMWEEK 3Cosmogony - Origin of the UniverseNature of .docxCruzIbarra161
 
Build a binary search tree that holds first names.Create a menu .docx
Build a binary search tree that holds first names.Create a menu .docxBuild a binary search tree that holds first names.Create a menu .docx
Build a binary search tree that holds first names.Create a menu .docxCruzIbarra161
 
Briefly describe the development of the string quartet. How would yo.docx
Briefly describe the development of the string quartet. How would yo.docxBriefly describe the development of the string quartet. How would yo.docx
Briefly describe the development of the string quartet. How would yo.docxCruzIbarra161
 
Briefly describe a time when you were misled by everyday observation.docx
Briefly describe a time when you were misled by everyday observation.docxBriefly describe a time when you were misled by everyday observation.docx
Briefly describe a time when you were misled by everyday observation.docxCruzIbarra161
 
Broadening Your Perspective 8-1The financial statements of Toots.docx
Broadening Your Perspective 8-1The financial statements of Toots.docxBroadening Your Perspective 8-1The financial statements of Toots.docx
Broadening Your Perspective 8-1The financial statements of Toots.docxCruzIbarra161
 
Briefly discuss the differences in the old Minimum Foundation Prog.docx
Briefly discuss the differences in the old Minimum Foundation Prog.docxBriefly discuss the differences in the old Minimum Foundation Prog.docx
Briefly discuss the differences in the old Minimum Foundation Prog.docxCruzIbarra161
 
Briefly compare and contrast EHRs, EMRs, and PHRs. Include the typic.docx
Briefly compare and contrast EHRs, EMRs, and PHRs. Include the typic.docxBriefly compare and contrast EHRs, EMRs, and PHRs. Include the typic.docx
Briefly compare and contrast EHRs, EMRs, and PHRs. Include the typic.docxCruzIbarra161
 
Brief Exercise 9-11Suppose Nike, Inc. reported the followin.docx
Brief Exercise 9-11Suppose Nike, Inc. reported the followin.docxBrief Exercise 9-11Suppose Nike, Inc. reported the followin.docx
Brief Exercise 9-11Suppose Nike, Inc. reported the followin.docxCruzIbarra161
 

More from CruzIbarra161 (20)

Business and Government Relations  Please respond to the following.docx
Business and Government Relations  Please respond to the following.docxBusiness and Government Relations  Please respond to the following.docx
Business and Government Relations  Please respond to the following.docx
 
Business Continuity Planning Explain how components of the busine.docx
Business Continuity Planning Explain how components of the busine.docxBusiness Continuity Planning Explain how components of the busine.docx
Business Continuity Planning Explain how components of the busine.docx
 
business and its environment Discuss the genesis, contributing fac.docx
business and its environment Discuss the genesis, contributing fac.docxbusiness and its environment Discuss the genesis, contributing fac.docx
business and its environment Discuss the genesis, contributing fac.docx
 
business and its environment Discuss the genesis, contributing facto.docx
business and its environment Discuss the genesis, contributing facto.docxbusiness and its environment Discuss the genesis, contributing facto.docx
business and its environment Discuss the genesis, contributing facto.docx
 
Business BUS 210 research outline1.Cover page 2.Table .docx
Business BUS 210 research outline1.Cover page 2.Table .docxBusiness BUS 210 research outline1.Cover page 2.Table .docx
Business BUS 210 research outline1.Cover page 2.Table .docx
 
BUS 439 International Human Resource ManagementInstructor Steven .docx
BUS 439 International Human Resource ManagementInstructor Steven .docxBUS 439 International Human Resource ManagementInstructor Steven .docx
BUS 439 International Human Resource ManagementInstructor Steven .docx
 
BUS 439 International Human Resource ManagementEmployee Value Pr.docx
BUS 439 International Human Resource ManagementEmployee Value Pr.docxBUS 439 International Human Resource ManagementEmployee Value Pr.docx
BUS 439 International Human Resource ManagementEmployee Value Pr.docx
 
Bullzeye is a discount retailer offering a wide range of products,.docx
Bullzeye is a discount retailer offering a wide range of products,.docxBullzeye is a discount retailer offering a wide range of products,.docx
Bullzeye is a discount retailer offering a wide range of products,.docx
 
Building on the work that you prepared for Milestones One through Th.docx
Building on the work that you prepared for Milestones One through Th.docxBuilding on the work that you prepared for Milestones One through Th.docx
Building on the work that you prepared for Milestones One through Th.docx
 
Budget Legislation Once the budget has been prepared by the vari.docx
Budget Legislation Once the budget has been prepared by the vari.docxBudget Legislation Once the budget has been prepared by the vari.docx
Budget Legislation Once the budget has been prepared by the vari.docx
 
Browsing the podcasts on iTunes or YouTube, listen to a few of Gramm.docx
Browsing the podcasts on iTunes or YouTube, listen to a few of Gramm.docxBrowsing the podcasts on iTunes or YouTube, listen to a few of Gramm.docx
Browsing the podcasts on iTunes or YouTube, listen to a few of Gramm.docx
 
Brown Primary Care Dental clinics Oral Health Initiative p.docx
Brown Primary Care Dental clinics Oral Health Initiative p.docxBrown Primary Care Dental clinics Oral Health Initiative p.docx
Brown Primary Care Dental clinics Oral Health Initiative p.docx
 
BUDDHISMWEEK 3Cosmogony - Origin of the UniverseNature of .docx
BUDDHISMWEEK 3Cosmogony - Origin of the UniverseNature of .docxBUDDHISMWEEK 3Cosmogony - Origin of the UniverseNature of .docx
BUDDHISMWEEK 3Cosmogony - Origin of the UniverseNature of .docx
 
Build a binary search tree that holds first names.Create a menu .docx
Build a binary search tree that holds first names.Create a menu .docxBuild a binary search tree that holds first names.Create a menu .docx
Build a binary search tree that holds first names.Create a menu .docx
 
Briefly describe the development of the string quartet. How would yo.docx
Briefly describe the development of the string quartet. How would yo.docxBriefly describe the development of the string quartet. How would yo.docx
Briefly describe the development of the string quartet. How would yo.docx
 
Briefly describe a time when you were misled by everyday observation.docx
Briefly describe a time when you were misled by everyday observation.docxBriefly describe a time when you were misled by everyday observation.docx
Briefly describe a time when you were misled by everyday observation.docx
 
Broadening Your Perspective 8-1The financial statements of Toots.docx
Broadening Your Perspective 8-1The financial statements of Toots.docxBroadening Your Perspective 8-1The financial statements of Toots.docx
Broadening Your Perspective 8-1The financial statements of Toots.docx
 
Briefly discuss the differences in the old Minimum Foundation Prog.docx
Briefly discuss the differences in the old Minimum Foundation Prog.docxBriefly discuss the differences in the old Minimum Foundation Prog.docx
Briefly discuss the differences in the old Minimum Foundation Prog.docx
 
Briefly compare and contrast EHRs, EMRs, and PHRs. Include the typic.docx
Briefly compare and contrast EHRs, EMRs, and PHRs. Include the typic.docxBriefly compare and contrast EHRs, EMRs, and PHRs. Include the typic.docx
Briefly compare and contrast EHRs, EMRs, and PHRs. Include the typic.docx
 
Brief Exercise 9-11Suppose Nike, Inc. reported the followin.docx
Brief Exercise 9-11Suppose Nike, Inc. reported the followin.docxBrief Exercise 9-11Suppose Nike, Inc. reported the followin.docx
Brief Exercise 9-11Suppose Nike, Inc. reported the followin.docx
 

Recently uploaded

Solving Puzzles Benefits Everyone (English).pptx
Solving Puzzles Benefits Everyone (English).pptxSolving Puzzles Benefits Everyone (English).pptx
Solving Puzzles Benefits Everyone (English).pptxOH TEIK BIN
 
Types of Journalistic Writing Grade 8.pptx
Types of Journalistic Writing Grade 8.pptxTypes of Journalistic Writing Grade 8.pptx
Types of Journalistic Writing Grade 8.pptxEyham Joco
 
KSHARA STURA .pptx---KSHARA KARMA THERAPY (CAUSTIC THERAPY)————IMP.OF KSHARA ...
KSHARA STURA .pptx---KSHARA KARMA THERAPY (CAUSTIC THERAPY)————IMP.OF KSHARA ...KSHARA STURA .pptx---KSHARA KARMA THERAPY (CAUSTIC THERAPY)————IMP.OF KSHARA ...
KSHARA STURA .pptx---KSHARA KARMA THERAPY (CAUSTIC THERAPY)————IMP.OF KSHARA ...M56BOOKSTORE PRODUCT/SERVICE
 
Roles & Responsibilities in Pharmacovigilance
Roles & Responsibilities in PharmacovigilanceRoles & Responsibilities in Pharmacovigilance
Roles & Responsibilities in PharmacovigilanceSamikshaHamane
 
Computed Fields and api Depends in the Odoo 17
Computed Fields and api Depends in the Odoo 17Computed Fields and api Depends in the Odoo 17
Computed Fields and api Depends in the Odoo 17Celine George
 
How to Make a Pirate ship Primary Education.pptx
How to Make a Pirate ship Primary Education.pptxHow to Make a Pirate ship Primary Education.pptx
How to Make a Pirate ship Primary Education.pptxmanuelaromero2013
 
Hierarchy of management that covers different levels of management
Hierarchy of management that covers different levels of managementHierarchy of management that covers different levels of management
Hierarchy of management that covers different levels of managementmkooblal
 
ECONOMIC CONTEXT - LONG FORM TV DRAMA - PPT
ECONOMIC CONTEXT - LONG FORM TV DRAMA - PPTECONOMIC CONTEXT - LONG FORM TV DRAMA - PPT
ECONOMIC CONTEXT - LONG FORM TV DRAMA - PPTiammrhaywood
 
Alper Gobel In Media Res Media Component
Alper Gobel In Media Res Media ComponentAlper Gobel In Media Res Media Component
Alper Gobel In Media Res Media ComponentInMediaRes1
 
भारत-रोम व्यापार.pptx, Indo-Roman Trade,
भारत-रोम व्यापार.pptx, Indo-Roman Trade,भारत-रोम व्यापार.pptx, Indo-Roman Trade,
भारत-रोम व्यापार.pptx, Indo-Roman Trade,Virag Sontakke
 
EPANDING THE CONTENT OF AN OUTLINE using notes.pptx
EPANDING THE CONTENT OF AN OUTLINE using notes.pptxEPANDING THE CONTENT OF AN OUTLINE using notes.pptx
EPANDING THE CONTENT OF AN OUTLINE using notes.pptxRaymartEstabillo3
 
call girls in Kamla Market (DELHI) 🔝 >༒9953330565🔝 genuine Escort Service 🔝✔️✔️
call girls in Kamla Market (DELHI) 🔝 >༒9953330565🔝 genuine Escort Service 🔝✔️✔️call girls in Kamla Market (DELHI) 🔝 >༒9953330565🔝 genuine Escort Service 🔝✔️✔️
call girls in Kamla Market (DELHI) 🔝 >༒9953330565🔝 genuine Escort Service 🔝✔️✔️9953056974 Low Rate Call Girls In Saket, Delhi NCR
 
Meghan Sutherland In Media Res Media Component
Meghan Sutherland In Media Res Media ComponentMeghan Sutherland In Media Res Media Component
Meghan Sutherland In Media Res Media ComponentInMediaRes1
 
internship ppt on smartinternz platform as salesforce developer
internship ppt on smartinternz platform as salesforce developerinternship ppt on smartinternz platform as salesforce developer
internship ppt on smartinternz platform as salesforce developerunnathinaik
 
Full Stack Web Development Course for Beginners
Full Stack Web Development Course  for BeginnersFull Stack Web Development Course  for Beginners
Full Stack Web Development Course for BeginnersSabitha Banu
 
History Class XII Ch. 3 Kinship, Caste and Class (1).pptx
History Class XII Ch. 3 Kinship, Caste and Class (1).pptxHistory Class XII Ch. 3 Kinship, Caste and Class (1).pptx
History Class XII Ch. 3 Kinship, Caste and Class (1).pptxsocialsciencegdgrohi
 
Final demo Grade 9 for demo Plan dessert.pptx
Final demo Grade 9 for demo Plan dessert.pptxFinal demo Grade 9 for demo Plan dessert.pptx
Final demo Grade 9 for demo Plan dessert.pptxAvyJaneVismanos
 
CELL CYCLE Division Science 8 quarter IV.pptx
CELL CYCLE Division Science 8 quarter IV.pptxCELL CYCLE Division Science 8 quarter IV.pptx
CELL CYCLE Division Science 8 quarter IV.pptxJiesonDelaCerna
 

Recently uploaded (20)

Solving Puzzles Benefits Everyone (English).pptx
Solving Puzzles Benefits Everyone (English).pptxSolving Puzzles Benefits Everyone (English).pptx
Solving Puzzles Benefits Everyone (English).pptx
 
ESSENTIAL of (CS/IT/IS) class 06 (database)
ESSENTIAL of (CS/IT/IS) class 06 (database)ESSENTIAL of (CS/IT/IS) class 06 (database)
ESSENTIAL of (CS/IT/IS) class 06 (database)
 
Types of Journalistic Writing Grade 8.pptx
Types of Journalistic Writing Grade 8.pptxTypes of Journalistic Writing Grade 8.pptx
Types of Journalistic Writing Grade 8.pptx
 
KSHARA STURA .pptx---KSHARA KARMA THERAPY (CAUSTIC THERAPY)————IMP.OF KSHARA ...
KSHARA STURA .pptx---KSHARA KARMA THERAPY (CAUSTIC THERAPY)————IMP.OF KSHARA ...KSHARA STURA .pptx---KSHARA KARMA THERAPY (CAUSTIC THERAPY)————IMP.OF KSHARA ...
KSHARA STURA .pptx---KSHARA KARMA THERAPY (CAUSTIC THERAPY)————IMP.OF KSHARA ...
 
OS-operating systems- ch04 (Threads) ...
OS-operating systems- ch04 (Threads) ...OS-operating systems- ch04 (Threads) ...
OS-operating systems- ch04 (Threads) ...
 
Roles & Responsibilities in Pharmacovigilance
Roles & Responsibilities in PharmacovigilanceRoles & Responsibilities in Pharmacovigilance
Roles & Responsibilities in Pharmacovigilance
 
Computed Fields and api Depends in the Odoo 17
Computed Fields and api Depends in the Odoo 17Computed Fields and api Depends in the Odoo 17
Computed Fields and api Depends in the Odoo 17
 
How to Make a Pirate ship Primary Education.pptx
How to Make a Pirate ship Primary Education.pptxHow to Make a Pirate ship Primary Education.pptx
How to Make a Pirate ship Primary Education.pptx
 
Hierarchy of management that covers different levels of management
Hierarchy of management that covers different levels of managementHierarchy of management that covers different levels of management
Hierarchy of management that covers different levels of management
 
ECONOMIC CONTEXT - LONG FORM TV DRAMA - PPT
ECONOMIC CONTEXT - LONG FORM TV DRAMA - PPTECONOMIC CONTEXT - LONG FORM TV DRAMA - PPT
ECONOMIC CONTEXT - LONG FORM TV DRAMA - PPT
 
Alper Gobel In Media Res Media Component
Alper Gobel In Media Res Media ComponentAlper Gobel In Media Res Media Component
Alper Gobel In Media Res Media Component
 
भारत-रोम व्यापार.pptx, Indo-Roman Trade,
भारत-रोम व्यापार.pptx, Indo-Roman Trade,भारत-रोम व्यापार.pptx, Indo-Roman Trade,
भारत-रोम व्यापार.pptx, Indo-Roman Trade,
 
EPANDING THE CONTENT OF AN OUTLINE using notes.pptx
EPANDING THE CONTENT OF AN OUTLINE using notes.pptxEPANDING THE CONTENT OF AN OUTLINE using notes.pptx
EPANDING THE CONTENT OF AN OUTLINE using notes.pptx
 
call girls in Kamla Market (DELHI) 🔝 >༒9953330565🔝 genuine Escort Service 🔝✔️✔️
call girls in Kamla Market (DELHI) 🔝 >༒9953330565🔝 genuine Escort Service 🔝✔️✔️call girls in Kamla Market (DELHI) 🔝 >༒9953330565🔝 genuine Escort Service 🔝✔️✔️
call girls in Kamla Market (DELHI) 🔝 >༒9953330565🔝 genuine Escort Service 🔝✔️✔️
 
Meghan Sutherland In Media Res Media Component
Meghan Sutherland In Media Res Media ComponentMeghan Sutherland In Media Res Media Component
Meghan Sutherland In Media Res Media Component
 
internship ppt on smartinternz platform as salesforce developer
internship ppt on smartinternz platform as salesforce developerinternship ppt on smartinternz platform as salesforce developer
internship ppt on smartinternz platform as salesforce developer
 
Full Stack Web Development Course for Beginners
Full Stack Web Development Course  for BeginnersFull Stack Web Development Course  for Beginners
Full Stack Web Development Course for Beginners
 
History Class XII Ch. 3 Kinship, Caste and Class (1).pptx
History Class XII Ch. 3 Kinship, Caste and Class (1).pptxHistory Class XII Ch. 3 Kinship, Caste and Class (1).pptx
History Class XII Ch. 3 Kinship, Caste and Class (1).pptx
 
Final demo Grade 9 for demo Plan dessert.pptx
Final demo Grade 9 for demo Plan dessert.pptxFinal demo Grade 9 for demo Plan dessert.pptx
Final demo Grade 9 for demo Plan dessert.pptx
 
CELL CYCLE Division Science 8 quarter IV.pptx
CELL CYCLE Division Science 8 quarter IV.pptxCELL CYCLE Division Science 8 quarter IV.pptx
CELL CYCLE Division Science 8 quarter IV.pptx
 

Counseling Disposition Reflection WorksheetDirections

  • 1. Counseling Disposition Reflection Worksheet Directions: Review the dispositions document and select three dispositions that you currently meet. Complete the chart by listing the dispositions met as well as a description of how you meet the disposition. Include a citation and paraphrase the definition. Please note: you do not need to be actively practicing to complete this worksheet. Disposition and Definition Description of how the disposition is met (75-100 words) 1. 2. 3. Directions: Now that you have identified dispositions that you currently meet, review the disposition document again and consider any dispositions that you do not meet. Complete the chart below by adding the two dispositions you do not meet as well as a preliminary plan in regards to how you plan to improve the identified dispositions. Disposition and Definition Description of how you plan to improve the disposition (75-100 words) 1.
  • 2. 2. © 2016. Grand Canyon University. All Rights Reserved. © 2014. Grand Canyon University. All Rights Reserved. 5Coalition Formation in Eastern Europe LEGISLATIVE STUDIES QUARTERLY, XXXII, 1, February 2007 5 JAMES N. DRUCKMAN ANDREW ROBERTS Northwestern University Communist Successor Parties And Coalition Formation In Eastern Europe One of the most distinctive features of new democracies is the presence of political parties associated with the old, repressive regime. This article investigates whether or not the Eastern European variant of these parties, which we call communist successor parties (CSPs), has affected coalition pol itics. It finds that CSPs do have significant effects on the dynamics of coalition formation. CSPs are less likely than other parties to be included in governing coalitions; coalitions that include CSPs are
  • 3. more likely to be oversized (that is, to include superfluous parties); and CSPs that make it into government are penalized, insofar as they receive less than their fair share of governing portfolios. We attribute these results to the salience of the regime divide—the affective dislike of many citizens for the legacies of communism. Our results extend research on coalition behavior to Eastern European contexts and show how affective dislike combined with vote-seeking motivations can affect governing behavior. How do coalitions form and function in new democracies? Most existing theories suggest that coalition formation in these countries should be driven by the same factors as in established democracies: the size and ideology of parties and the institutional framework in which they operate (see Martin and Stevenson 2001 for a summary of theories). In this article, we look at one significant fact about new democracies that may produce a different sort of coalition politics. Most new democracies are distinguished by the presence of successors to the former ruling parties. These successors may simply be accepted as normal players in the democratic game, but there are good reasons to believe they will be treated differently by other parties. After all, the
  • 4. successor parties are associated with regimes that, at best, restricted fundamental human rights and, at worst, murdered or imprisoned significant portions of their countries’ populations. It is thus reasonable 6 James N. Druckman and Andrew Roberts to expect that these parties will be seen as more than si mply bearers of legislative strength and ideology. To address this issue, we examine coalition politics in 15 Eastern European countries. Specifically, we studied the effect on coalition formation of what we call communist successor parties (CSPs), the parties that are the organizational successors to the former ruling communist parties. We focused on three aspects of coalition politics: Do CSPs enter government to the same extent as other parties? Do the governments that CSPs enter differ from governments composed of other parties? And are CSPs allocated a proportional share of ministries when they enter government? In all three cases, we found evidence that CSPs are treated differently than other parties, even when we controlled
  • 5. for their legislative strength and ideology. We believe that these anomalies stem from a combination of affective dislike on the part of voters and party activists for CSPs and the vote-seeking motivations of party leaders. Party leaders appear to follow the lead of their electorates and party activists in shunning CSPs or limiting the CSPs’ influence on politics. Our findings are particularly interesting because there has been relatively little study of coalition formation in new democracies. Consistent with recent institutional theories of coalition behavior (for example, Martin and Stevenson 2001 and Strøm, Budge, and Laver 1994), the results imply that understanding coalitional politics requires contextual knowledge about the substance of national politics. Specifically, our findings suggest that scholars should pay more attention to the affective attitudes of party electorates and elites toward rival parties. In cases where there is strong affective dislike of a particular party, vote-seeking motivations may be as, or perhaps even more, important than office- and policy-seeking motivations of parties. I. Communist Successor Parties Few topics in postcommunist politics have been studied as intensively as communist successor parties, the parties that are the
  • 6. organizational successors to the old ruling parties. A review of the literature on this topic reveals at least two books, two edited volumes, and 18 articles devoted exclusively to the comparative analysis of these parties.1 Taking into account articles devoted to individual successor parties or to the place of CSPs in party systems substantially adds to this total. No other type of party—liberal, agrarian, nationalist, or even extremist—has received comparable study. 7Coalition Formation in Eastern Europe Why have these parties attracted so much attention? In the first place, it came as a surprise to many scholars that these parties survived and, in some cases, transformed themselves. It was assumed that parties so closely associated with a repressive dictatorship would quickly fall by the wayside when faced with genuine competition.2 Moreover, it seemed unlikely that these parties would be able to change their ways, given the heavy baggage that they carried from the past. Scholars expected these parties to remain as authoritarian and ideologically extreme as they had always been. For this reason, the ability of CSPs to win elections, first in Lithuania and Poland and later in
  • 7. other countries, led many observers to worry about a possible reversion to nondemocratic politics. When the election of these parties did not portend a return to communism, scholars wanted to know how some of these parties were able to transform themselves into democratic parties. Finally, students of postcommunist politics were interested in how citizens and politicians would react to these parties. CSPs were intimately connected with some of the most repressive regimes in human history. Would citizens be able to forgive and forget after the fall of communism? Or would they hold grudges against these parties for the destruction their predecessors had inflicted? How important, in short, were legacies of the past? A survey of the literature devoted to these parties finds that it is focused almost entirely on party development.3 Virtually all of this work addresses the same two questions: (1) What explains the success of CSPs, either in merely surviving or in winning elections? and (2) What explains a CSP’s ability or inability to transform into a normal democratic party? Most of this literature can thus be classed as addressing the causes of these parties rather than their effects. Instead of revisiting this research, we ask a different, and in some sense, more-consequential question: do CSPs matter politically?
  • 8. Research has not yet shown that these parties have had a definite effect on politics in the region. Did it matter that CSPs managed to survive or transform themselves in the countries of Eastern Europe? Did they actually affect the substance of politics in the region? In essence, ours is the “so what?” question. We focus specifically on the dynamics of government formation and portfolio allocation. These areas are particularly good for tests of these questions because they have bred a large literature (giving us a baseline of comparison) and they are readily quantifiable. We believe that these questions are significant not only because their answers may provide a validation of previous work, but also because they have important consequences for governance in the region. 8 James N. Druckman and Andrew Roberts Government formation and the allocation of portfolios have been shown in numerous studies to shape policy outcomes and general well - being (see, for example, Klingemann, Hofferbert, and Budge 1994 and Lijphart 1999). Thus, if CSPs alter the dynamics of coalition politics, then this influence could ultimately have profound effects on the politics
  • 9. of the region. II. CSPs and Coalition Theory Just as studies on Eastern European politics have paid scant attention to how CSPs affect coalition governance, the literature on coalition behavior has given limited consideration to governing dynamics in Eastern Europe, instead focusing largely on Western Europe (see, however, Blondel and Müller-Rommel 2001; Druckman and Roberts 2005, N.d., and Grzymala-Busse 2001). That said, coalition theory, more generally, provides reasons to expect CSPs to matter. Over the last 20 years, researchers have shown how various external constraints affect coalition behavior (see, for example, De Winter 1995; Druckman and Thies 2002; Huber 1996; Laver and Schofield 1990, 195–215; Martin and Stevenson 2001, 35–38; and Mershon 1996). Most of these constraints come from institutions and include such things as formation rules (for instance, investiture rules), cabinet operation rules (such as votes of no confidence), legislative rules (such as dissolution rules), and party rules. Most relevant for us, given our interest in CSPs, is the impact of party rules. Strøm, Budge, and Laver (1994) explain that Party leaders may declare that they will, or will not, form
  • 10. particular coalitions. . . . The systematic exclusion of certain parties from coalition bargaining is the most striking party constraint found with any regularity. . . . The examples of the Gaullists or Communists in the French Fourth Republic, Sinn Féin in Ireland, or the Italian Communists in the 1950s show that certain parties, as a consequence of their strong “antisystem” stance, can effectively be discounted as members of any potential government. (317) CSPs in Eastern Europe differ from these parties insofar as they have generally not been systematically excluded from government formation (Strøm, Budge, and Laver focus on Western Europe; also see Martin and Stevenson 2001, 37, 46; and Mershon 1994, 57; 2002, 40– 41). Yet the basic idea that specific types of parties can alter the dynamics of coalition bargaining extends to the case of CSPs. Indeed, Strøm, Budge, and Laver (1994, 317) even acknowledge that “Besides antisystem parties [with whom other parties refuse to bargain], taboos are often 9Coalition Formation in Eastern Europe attached to parties associated with the previous political regimes,
  • 11. especially undemocratic ones.” These types of parties impose incentives “that change the calculus of the decision maker” (Laver and Schofield 1990, 202). In the case of CSPs, constraints come from the internal party politics and party electorates of the nonsuccessor parties (see Strøm 1990a). That is, party activists and voters of the other parties may oppose coalitions with CSPs for affective reasons unrelated to party strength and ideology. Party leaders will heed these preferences because, in addition to pursuing office and policy, they pursue votes and need to maintain support from activists and voters. The underlying reason for these attitudes is what a considerable literature has referred to as the “regime divide”—the affective dislike of former opponents of communism for those associated in any way with the communist system (Kitschelt et al. 1999).4 The brutality of the communist regime is said to have led victims of the regime to visceral distaste for representatives of that regime. In societies flat- tened by communism—and thus lacking many of the political cleavages found in established democracies—the division between supporters and opponents of the old regime appears to be one of the strongest political cleavages. Just as the Civil War generated lasting
  • 12. political cleavages in the United States, the trauma of 40 years of communism should leave a lasting imprint on postcommunist politics. This emotional distaste may be so great that it overwhelms the desire of some CSPs to draw a thick line between themselves and the previous ruling parties and to present themselves as normal players in the democratic game.5 For many citizens, and even politicians, the mere thought of a CSP provokes a negative emotional reaction. We should add that such a reaction is not usually in response to the current ideology of the party—several of these parties have quite moderate ideologies—or to its legislative strength—none of these parties dominates politics in the way that the former rulers did. We believe there are two ways in which the regime divide might affect coalition politics.6 First, it is possible that party elites affectively dislike CSPs so intensely that the elites sacrifice some of the benefits of office and policy in order to punish CSPs. This dislike may reflect instrumental consequences generated by intraparty politics. Strøm, Budge, and Laver (1994, 318) explain that “senior politicians interact with activists in their own parties. Party leaders may believe that some coalitions would be sufficiently detrimental to their recruitment of
  • 13. candidates or activists to be avoided under all circumstances. Or they may believe that the benefits of a potential coalition would be 10 James N. Druckman and Andrew Roberts outweighed by the costs their own activists would impose in irate retaliation. . . . [T]hese risks may induce party leaders to refrain from otherwise attractive coalitions [for example, with CSPs].” Second, and perhaps more important, the regime divide may work through the general electorate. In addition to seeking office and policy outcomes, parties also seek to maximize the votes they receive in present and future elections (Strøm 1990a). If party electorates are sufficiently opposed to coalitions with CSPs for the affective reasons we mentioned, then party elites will likely follow the electorates’ lead. Elites will avoid such coalitions or find ways to distance themselves from CSPs or keep CSPs in check within such coalitions. All of these strategies are motivated by a desire to avoid losing votes in future elections.7 As evidence of this vote-seeking motivation, Grzymala-Busse (2001) has shown that parties that form coalitions with CSPs are
  • 14. punished more strongly at the polls than parties that do not. Anecdotal evidence supports this view as well. Consider the active movement in the Czech Republic, spanning from left to right, called “One Doesn’t Speak with Communists” or the recent mobilizations of the Hungarian Fidesz party and the Polish Law and Justice Party (PiS) against the vestiges of communism embodied in quite liberal CSPs. The fact that parties in many states of the region campaign on the anticommunism and anti-CSP issue even today, 15 years after the transition, indicates that the issue must still touch a nerve with voters.8 III. Hypotheses Given this logic, we expect that the presence of CSPs and this regime divide will affect at least three areas of coalition formation. The first is participation in government. While CSPs surely desire to participate in government, it is possible that they are rarely invited to join governments. This exclusion could occur because of some combination of affective dislike, intraparty consequences, and/or fear of electoral consequences. Theories of the regime divide would thus predict that CSPs are less likely to serve in government, all other things being equal. The same conclusion could flow from a consideration of
  • 15. the CSPs themselves. If they are so rigid because of their authoritarian past that they are unable to compromise with other parties, then they will be less likely to participate in coalition governments. It is important to consider the ceteris paribus clause here. Are CSPs less likely to serve in government, all else being equal? The 11Coalition Formation in Eastern Europe important control variable is party ideology. CSPs may be discrimi- nated against because they are extremists, that is, because they have not broken ties with the past and renounced the politics of the old regime. A number of theories of government formation argue that ideology matters for government participation (for instance, Laver 1998). We wished to determine if the mere fact of being a CSP leads to decreased participation regardless of ideology. Does the CSP variable add any explanatory power above and beyond ideology? Are these parties excluded from power merely for being who they are? We discuss our test of this hypothesis in Section V. The second possible effect of the regime divide is on cabinet types. If there is intense affective dislike for CSPs, then they
  • 16. might only enter government as part of surplus majority coalitions. This is for two reasons. First, oversized coalitions help other parties to distance themselves from the former communists in the eyes of voters and thus minimize electoral punishment. Second, the inclusion of extra parties helps to moderate the possibly extreme or reactionary policy proposals of the CSPs and the concomitant uncertainty that a CSP may bring to governing (Dodd 1976; Riker 1962). The formation of an oversized coalition with the former communists was widely noted after the Hungarian elections of 1994.9 We aimed to determine if this tendency toward oversized coalitions has more-general applicability. We discuss our test of this hypothesis in Section VI. The third effect of CSPs is on the allocation of portfolios once a coalition has formed. In Western Europe, coalition parties tend to receive portfolios in nearly one-to-one proportion to their seat share, with a slight small-party bias.10 Dislike for CSPs, however, may lead the successor parties to be compensated less than proportionally, as other parties try to put distance between themselves and the former communists for the benefit of their electorates or party activists. Even when CSPs form governments, they may have to offer their
  • 17. coalition partners excess portfolios in order to induce the other parties to join the government. On the other hand, the possible authoritarian tendencies of these parties may lead them to demand more than their proportionate share. We discuss our test of these hypotheses in Section VII. One final note is that there are reasons to expect, contrary to our hypotheses, that CSPs are treated the same as other parties. If other parties care mainly about office and policy, as has been emphasized in many theories, then these parties have strong incentives to negotiate with CSPs as they would with other parties. There are likely to be costs to discriminating against CSPs, and parties concerned only about office or policy should try to avoid these costs. 12 James N. Druckman and Andrew Roberts Our null hypothesis is thus that CSPs are not treated anomalously in government formation. If we cannot reject the null, then we are left to conclude that the party-specific history of the CSPs in Eastern European politics is not a significant factor in explaining government formation in this region. We would view a rejection of the null
  • 18. as evidence consistent with how constraints stemming from party rules (Strøm, Budge, and Laver 1994) in general and Eastern European CSPs in particular shape coalition politics. IV. Data We tested these hypotheses with a new dataset that includes government formation decisions in Eastern Europe. The Eastern European data come from nearly all coalitions in the 15 Eastern European countries listed in Table 1, starting with the first democrati- cally elected government in each country and continuing through 2002.11 This sample thus includes all of the parliamentary democracies in Eastern Europe for the lifetime of their existence. We collected the bulk of these data from Keesing’s Contemporary Archives, although in a few instances we drew on country-specific sources, including data directly from the country’s legislative archives. For each government, we identified all parties in government, every party with at least one seat in parliament (at the point of govern- ment formation), whether or not the party served in the previous government, the seat share of the party, whether or not the party was a communist successor party, the party type of each party, and the partisan affiliation of each minister.
  • 19. To determine if a party was a CSP, we followed Bozóki and Ishiyama (2002).12 We drew the party type variable from Armingeon and Careja’s (2004) work. This variable labels each party as one of 17 types specified by Lane, McKay, and Newton (1997): communist, postcommunist, left-socialist, socialist, pensioners, greens, agrarian, liberal, religious, conservative, nationalist, ultra-right, ethnic, regional, alliance, protest, and no-label. We labeled a small number of parties not included in their dataset ourselves. We used the party types as a proxy for ideology in the absence of more-direct measures. We should note that CSP is not a party type but a separate dummy variable; for example, some CSPs are classified as “communists,” while others are “socialists.” (We will discuss the details shortly.) For most of the article, our unit of analysis is the party, since we are interested in explaining the inclusion of a party in government and the proportion of portfolios each party receives. We also use the 13Coalition Formation in Eastern Europe TA B L
  • 41. sl at ur e se at , o ve r t he c as es o f a ll go ve rn m en ts fo rm
  • 43. ta l o f 2 56 pa rt ie s ou t o f a to ta l o f 59 3 pa rt ie s in th
  • 48. on e H un ga ri an g ov er nm en t. 14 James N. Druckman and Andrew Roberts coalition as our unit when we consider the influence of CSPs on cabinet types. In total, there are 76 coalition governments, 593 parties in the legislature, and 256 parties in government. In Table 1, we report, for each Eastern European country, the number of governments, the number of parties in the legislature and government, the years of the first and most recent governments, and the frequency of CSPs in the
  • 49. legislature and in government. V. Government Participation Are CSPs discriminated against in government formation? Table 1 gives an indication of the prevalence of CSPs in Eastern Europe. Of the 593 parties that received legislative sets in our dataset, 62 (11%) were CSPs. As far as government participation goes, CSPs constituted 32 of 256 parties (13%) in government. On the surface there does not appear to be discrimination, but these results do not control for party size and ideology. Table 2 is a cross-tabulation of CSP and party type. As mentioned, CSPs come from various different types (that is, party type reflects ideology, whereas CSP status reflects historical origin). The table shows that CSPs fall into five different party types: communist, postcommunist, left-socialist, socialist, and ethnic. Note that CSPs make up only 31% (62/202) of these five party types (the other 69% of these party types are not CSPs). This distinction will later allow us to control for ideology. There are other parties that share the same ideological space but do not carry the historical baggage of the CSPs.
  • 50. To determine the causes of government participation, we would, ideally, examine the factors that lead to the creation of different coalitions. This analysis would require specifying all of the possible coalitions that might form and then measuring all factors that might affect formation, including ideology and institutional variables (Martin and Stevenson 2001). We did not have access to all of these variables, and thus we conducted a more-exploratory analysis to determine if there is any basis for believing that CSPs are treated differently than other parties. Our dependent variable in these regressions is whether or not a party participated in government. Because our dependent variable is dichoto- mous, we used logit regressions in all of the analyses that follow. We identified a number of independent variables that might affect government participation. First, conventional theories of size predict that larger parties are more likely to participate in government (Martin and Stevenson 2001). To account for this possibility, one of our 15Coalition Formation in Eastern Europe TABLE 2 CSP Legislative Parties
  • 51. Party Typea Not CSP CSP Total Communist 1 (number) 8 9 11% (row %) 89% 100% 1% (column %) 13% 5% Postcommunist 2 18 20 10% 90% 100% 1% 29% 10% Left-socialist 14 1 15 93% 7% 100% 10% 2% 7% Socialist 72 33 105 69% 31% 100% 51% 53% 52% Ethnic 51 2 53 96% 4% 100% 36% 3% 26% Total 140 62 202 69% 31% 100% 100% 100% 100% aTable includes only the parties belonging to the 5 listed party types. Not included are the following other party types, comprising 391 parties: Pensioners, Green, Agrarian, Liberal, Religious, Conservative, Nationalist, Ultraright, Regional, Alliance,
  • 52. Protest, Non-Label/others, for a total of 17 types (and 593 legislative parties). Source: Armingeon and Careja 2004. independent variables is the seat share of each party in parliament.13 A second variable that might affect participation is incumbency (Martin and Stevenson 2001; Strøm, Budge, and Laver 1994). Parties that have served in the previous government are more likely to serve in the current government; they are part of the status quo. Finally, we included a measure of party ideology. Most theories of government formation postulate that parties are at least partially motivated by policy. Parties thus judge the suitability of coalition partners by their policy stances. As a result, a party’s ideology will help to determine whether or not it enters government. Our measure of ideology is less precise than those of other studies, which use expert 16 James N. Druckman and Andrew Roberts judgments or analyses of party manifestos to pinpoint specific ideological locations; such measures are not yet publicly available for Eastern Europe. We therefore sought to capture ideology with Armingeon and Careja’s (2004) coding of party types for all political
  • 53. parties in Eastern Europe. As previously noted, this measure classifies all parties in Eastern Europe into one of 17 party types, and each CSP is classified into one of these party types. Because CSP itself is not a party type, when we added party type controls we were able to control for the ideology of CSPs (see Table 2). We ran all analysis with and without the incumbency variable, because including incumbency reduces the size of the data (from 593 to 475 parties), since the initial governments are excluded. Fortunately, the results are virtually identical, regardless of whether or not we include incumbency; thus, in Table 3, we only present the results that include incumbency (since it is itself significant). We therefore report results with 475 cases rather than 593. We report one-tailed tests because we clearly predicted a negative relationship between CSP, our key variable, and government participation. Model 1 tests whether or not seat share and incumbency states predict participation in government. The results for both variables are highly significant and in the correct direction. Larger parties and incumbents are more likely to participate in government. In Model 2, we introduced the variable in which we are interested theoretically. The
  • 54. communist successor party variable is highly significant, substantively large, and, as expected, has a negative sign. CSPs are far less likely to serve in governments than are other parties with the same seat share. We next introduced controls for ideology, aiming to determine if the penalty for being a CSP is due to the party’s ideology or to the mere fact of being a CSP. In Model 3, we added dummy variables for all five party types of the CSPs (communist, postcommunist, left- socialist, socialist, and ethnic). The results indicate that the CSP penalty is robust to the addition of these ideological controls: the CSP variable emerges as both negative and significant, while four of the five dummies are insignificant (postcommunists are marginally advantaged).14 To get a sense of the substantive impact of the CSP effect, we conducted a simulation using Clarify (Tomz, Wittenberg, and King 1999). Setting all other variables at their means, we found that being a CSP reduces a party’s chances of serving in government on average by 19% (from 42% to 23%).15 This appears to us to be a quite substantial effect. In sum, we have found that communist successor parties are less likely than other parties to participate in government, even
  • 55. when we control for size, incumbency, and ideology. 17Coalition Formation in Eastern Europe TABLE 3 Determinants of Government Participation Dependent Variable: Whether or not a given party participated in government (1 = participated, 0 = did not participate) Model Independent Variable (1) (2) (3) Legislative seat share 5.95** 6.57** 6.76*** (.99) (1.06) (1.1) Incumbencya 1.37** 1.35** 1.34*** (.22) (.22) (.22) CSP –0.70* –1.08** (.41) (.52) Communist party 0.085 (1.2) Postcommunist party 1.11 (.86) Left-socialist party –0.52 (.67) Socialist party 0.26
  • 56. (.31) Ethnic party –0.25 (.38) Constant –1.56** –1.56** –1.63*** (.17) (.17) (.20) Log-likelihood –268.4 –267.1 –265.6 Observations 475 475 475 aThe number of cases reduces to 475 because we exclude all first governments in which there were no incumbents. Results are robust if we instead include all first governments without the incumbency variable. Note: Entries are logit coefficients, with standard errors in parentheses. ***p ≤ .01; **p ≤ .05; *p ≤ .1, one-tailed tests. VI. Cabinet Types Although CSPs are discriminated against in government forma- tion, some CSPs do ultimately enter cabinets. In this section, we address the question of what these cabinets look like: what sort of cabinets do CSPs enter? Most theories of government formation predict the formation of some form of minimal winning coalition, but there have 18 James N. Druckman and Andrew Roberts been several attempts to account for minority and oversized
  • 57. coalitions (see Martin and Stevenson 2001; Strøm 1990b; and Volden and Carrubba 2004). What these theories explicitly do not hypothesize is that certain parties will tend to join one type of coalition more than others. We argue, however, that the desire of most democratic parties to distance themselves from communist successor parties might lead them to be part of distinctive coalitions. In particular, CSPs should more commonly end up in oversized coalitions. Oversized coalitions would serve two purposes for non-CSPs. First, they would help protect non- CSPs’ reputations. Accountability is harder in large coalitions because of the difficulty in pinpointing responsibility. Parties that have to enter coalitions with the former communists might demand to add extra parties, so as not to look like they are too close to the CSPs. Second, extra parties would help to restrain the communists and promote consensus in policymaking (and also lessen the uncertainty involved with predicting CSP behavior; see Dodd 1976 and Riker 1962). The more parties that are included in the coalition, the less influence the communists will have, since voting in the council of ministers typically gives each minister one vote.
  • 58. Our data confirm this expectation. Table 4 shows the percentage of cabinet types including and not including CSPs.16 A full 78% (25/ 32) of governments with CSPs are oversized, compared to only 43% (19/44) of governments without CSPs (z = 3.05; p < .01 for one- tailed difference-of-proportions test). While minimal winning coalitions and minority coalitions are common—constituting 56.5% (9/44 are minority and 16/44 are minimal winning) of the total—in governments without CSPs, they are quite rare—only 21.5% (3/32 are minority and 4/32 are minimal winning)—in governments that include a CSP. These results raise an intriguing question: if coalitions add surplus parties to protect themselves against CSPs, then why do they include CSPs in the first place? We have some preliminary evidence that suggests that, in most cases, governing parties include CSPs because it is necessary if the parties hope to maintain a governing majority. We show this necessity by exploring the rate at which CSPs in govern- ment are pivotal. A party is pivotal when its removal changes a majority coalition to a minority coalition (Schofield and Laver 1985). We found that 69% (22/32) of the CSPs in government are pivotal, compared to only 39% (87/224) of non-CSPs in government (z = 3.21; p <
  • 59. .01 for two-tailed difference-of-proportions test). Moreover, nearly all of the ten nonpivotal CSPs in government belonged to exceptional coalitions: three of them belonged to minority coalitions in which no party was 19Coalition Formation in Eastern Europe TABLE 4 Cabinet Types in Eastern Europe Cabinet Type No CSPs in Government A CSP in Government Total Minority 20.5% (9) 9.0% (3) 16% (12) Minimal Winning 36.0% (16) 12.5% (4) 26% (20) Oversized 43.0% (19) 78.0% (25) 58% (44) Total 100% (44) 100% (32) 100% (76) pivotal by definition, and six of them belonged to near-unity coalitions. In the latter cases, parties controlled approximately 91% of the legis- lative seats, meaning that, to be pivotal, a particular party would have to be composed of a near majority itself.17 In short, we find that CSPs are usually included in governments because they are necessary for a majority. Of course, one may
  • 60. question the desirability of having a majority when a minority without a CSP is sustainable (see, for example, Strøm 1990b). But there are good reasons why parties might prefer to join majority coalitions in transition countries. Majorities should help coalitions to pass legislation. In times of major reforms, and particularly reforms with enormous distribu- tional consequences, parties would like the security of having a reliable majority in parliament. Also, parliamentary voting in new democracies tends to be unstable, and parties may not be able to discipline their members (Andrews 2002). There is also a high rate of party switching among members of parliament (Kreuzer and Pettai 2003; Shabad and Slomczynski 2004). This switching makes majorities even more important, and we suspect it enables CSPs to enter governments— governments which, in turn, try to protect themselves from CSPs by forming oversized coalitions that dilute the visibility and influence of the former communists.18 VII. Ministerial Allocation We now turn to our third dependent variable. The way that port- folios are allocated to parties in a governing coalition has been closely studied in Western Europe. This research has revealed one of the stron-
  • 61. gest relations in political science. Gamson’s Law postulates that each coalition party receives portfolios in direct proportion to the percentage 20 James N. Druckman and Andrew Roberts of seats that it contributes to the coalition (see Gamson 1961).19 For example, a party with 30% of the seats in a coalition receives about 30% of the portfolios. It is not clear if Gamson’s Law is a universal law, applying in all contexts, or is specific to the circumstances of Western Europe. One possible challenge to the law comes from communist successor parties in Eastern Europe. If these parties behave differently or are treated differently than other parties, then this bias might show up in the process of portfolio allocation. Indeed, the regime divide theory argues that rival parties harbor negative feelings toward CSPs. This ill will may result in CSPs being undercompensated relative to proportionality. Other parties may be reluctant to grant CSPs their fair share of ministries. In turn, CSPs may be willing to sacrifice some of their fair share in order to be allowed
  • 62. into governments. On the other hand—and contrary to the general regime-divide theoretical framework—if CSPs maintain their authori- tarian ways from communism, then they might be expected to demand more than their fair share of portfolios. Winner-take-all norms were common under communism and might be expected to persist, particu- larly for successor parties. In this case, we would expect CSPs to receive more than their fair share of portfolios. To test these possibilities, our dependent variable is the percentage of portfolios allocated to the party in question. Previous work has identified two independent variables that affect the percentage of port- folios that a party receives. One is the percentage of legislative seats that a party contributes to the coalition (a la Gamson’s Law; see, for example, Browne and Franklin 1973). We refer to this variable as seat share. The other variable is whether or not a party is a formateur. There remains controversy, however, about whether formateurs tend to be under- or overcompensated (see Ansolabehere et al. 2005; Baron and Ferejohn 1989; Harrington 1990; Morelli 1999; and Warwick and Druckman 2001, 2006). We add to these variables a new variable indi-
  • 63. cating whether or not a party is a communist successor party. This is the variable we are interested in theoretically.20 Following Warwick and Druckman (2001), we ran OLS regres- sions without an intercept, although the results are robust to alternative specifications, such as including an intercept. Because we left out the intercept, we did not include main-effect dummy variables, as this step would have been akin to including an intercept. Thus, both the formateur variable and the CSP variable are interacted with the seat share variable. If the CSP interaction term is significant, then this result indicates that CSPs are allocated portfolios nonproportionally. 21Coalition Formation in Eastern Europe TABLE 5 Portfolio Allocation in Eastern Europe (standard errors in parentheses) Dependent Variable: Party’s share of portfolios Model Independent Variable (4) (5) (6) Seat contribution 0.94*** 0.92*** 0.94*** (.02) (.04) (.04) Formateur status x Seat contribution 0.03 0.08*
  • 64. (.04) (.05) CSP x Seat contribution –0.17*** (0.04) Observations 256 256 256 Note: Entries are OLS unstandardized slope coefficients, with intercepts set equal to 0. ***p ≤ .01; **p ≤ .05; * p ≤ .1, two-tailed tests. Table 5 presents our regression results.21 (We report two-tailed significance tests because of our dueling hypotheses about the CSP effect.) In Model 4, we included only the seat share variable. The variable is highly significant and nearly proportional (beta = 0.94). Model 5 included the formateur interaction term. This variable is insignificant, indicating that formateurs are neither under- nor over- compensated relative to their seat shares. The seat share variable remains significant and substantively almost identical. We next included the CSP interaction variable. Model 6 shows that this variable is both highly significant and substantively important. The negative sign on the variable indicates that CSPs receive less than their proportional share of portfolios. The effect is also substantively important. Communist successor parties receive approximately 17% less than their fair share of portfolios. We also see in this
  • 65. regression that, once we control for CSP status, formateurs receive a slight bonus. Thus, non-CSP formateurs take more than their share. This pattern differs from that found in Western Europe, a distinction we have explored in other work (see Druckman and Roberts 2005). In short, CSPs are penalized in portfolio allocation. The fact that they are penalized lends itself to an important interpretation. At the outset of this section, we suggested two possible outcomes to alloca- tion: If CSPs act like their predecessors, then they will demand over- compensation. If they are the object of other parties’ disdain, then CSPs 22 James N. Druckman and Andrew Roberts will be undercompensated. Our finding of undercompensation indicates that the decisive factor is not the CSPs themselves but the attitude of other parties toward them. VIII. Time and Space These results convince us that CSPs elicit distinctive coalition dynamics in Eastern Europe, but there may also be variations across time or space. First, our theory is based on the affective dislike
  • 66. of voters and elites toward the former communists. It is likely that these emotions will diminish over time as memories fade and the former communists become accepted players in the democratic game. To probe this possibility, we reran our analyses, cutting our sample at its midpoint of 1996. We found that the two time periods looked very similar. All of the aspects of CSP discrimination we uncovered in the previous analyses appear both before and after 1996. (We experimented with various other time splits, and in no instance did we find a significant time effect.) While this result strikes us as surprising, it does correspond with qualitative observations of the region. In three of the most recent elections in the region (in Poland, Hungary, and the Czech Republic), a key—perhaps the dominant—element in the campaigns of right-wing parties was an evocation of the dangers or injustice of letting CSPs rule. The regime divide appears to have considerable power to structure politics even 15 years after the transition. Eastern Europe also features considerable variation over space. As Kitschelt et al. (1999) note, Eastern Europe exhibits considerably more spatial diversity than other regions in the world. Indeed,
  • 67. many analyses have divided the region into more-advanced and less- advanced halves (King 2000; Vachudova and Snyder 1997). By “more advanced,” we mean countries widely considered to have attained standards of democracy and development close to those of the established democ- racies of Western Europe. By contrast, “less-advanced” countries have significant shortcomings in the functioning of both democracy and the economy. The more-advanced countries entered the European Union (EU) in May 2004, they have been more democratic as measured by Freedom House, and they have higher incomes and higher scores on the World Bank’s Human Development Index. The less- advanced coun- tries did not enter the EU and have significantly lower ratings on the other measures. For the purposes of our analyses, the key fact would be whether or not attitudes toward the former communists differ between these two groups of countries. We do not have direct evidence on this point,22 23Coalition Formation in Eastern Europe but we have some reason to believe that there are differences.
  • 68. More- advanced countries have a considerably larger middl e class, which sees communism as having limited its opportunities to attain Western standards of living. These individuals are thus more likely to hold a grudge against the CSPs and punish cooperation with them. In less- advanced countries, by contrast, the middle class is much smaller, and there is a much larger lower class whose position has worsened since the end of communism. As a result, there should be greater acceptance of the representatives of the old regime. It is possible, of course, that we may witness the opposite effects. In less-advanced countries, the communist regime was typically more repressive than in the more-advanced ones. As a result, it is possible that CSPs will be viewed more negatively in less-advanced countries and discrimination will be more extreme there. To test these ideas, we divided the sample into two groups. The main variable we used to distinguish them was their average Freedom House score during the 1990s. Our advanced countries included Czechoslovakia, the Czech Republic, Estonia, Hungary, Latvia, Lithuania, Poland, and Slovenia; our non-advanced countries included Albania, Bulgaria, Croatia, Macedonia, Romania, Serbia, and Slovakia.
  • 69. This division also corresponds to the first wave of accession to the EU, with the exception of Slovakia, which is classed as less advanced (the results are robust to classifying Slovakia as more advanced). To determine if CSPs are treated differently when it comes to government formation in the two groups of countries, we added two variables to Table 3, Model 3: a dummy variable distinguishing between more-advanced and less-advanced countries, and an interaction between this more-advanced/less-advanced variable and the CSP variable. The interaction is marginally significant (p ≤ .15). It is thus possible that the regime divide is stronger in the more- advanced countries. Citizens of these countries might view the old regime as having impeded their development and thus wish to punish the successors to these parties. Citizens of less-advanced countries are less likely to harbor negative affect toward communism and thus are less likely to penalize parties associated with the old regime. We emphasize, however, that this supposition is quite speculative, given the marginal significance of the result. Also, when we turn to cabinet types and portfolio allocation, we find no significant differences across regions. Cabinets with CSPs have a higher likelihood of being
  • 70. over- sized than those that do not include CSPs, in both less-advanced and more-advanced countries, and portfolio allocation in both types of countries awards less than a proportional number of portfolios to CSPs.23 24 James N. Druckman and Andrew Roberts IX. Conclusion Although scholars of parliamentary government have often recognized that the identity of individual parties matters for coalition formation, this fact has not often been included in quantitative studies. Preference has been given to the more analytically tractable concepts of legislative strength and ideology. The experience of Eastern European countries provides an inter- esting example of how party identity may matter for coalition formation. These countries have recently emerged from dictatorships that have left important scars on the polity. These scars remain fresh because representatives of the old regime continue to contest elections in the new regime. There are thus good reasons to believe that other parties, and particularly their electorates, will view communist successor parties
  • 71. not only in terms of their legislative strength and ideology, but also in terms of their identity as representatives of the old regime. In this article, we have shown that this bias emerges in three facets of government formation. Communist successor parties are less likely to enter government than other parties, and when they do enter government, they tend to be part of oversized coalitions and to be allocated less than their proportional share of portfolios. CSPs do suffer discrimination at the hands of other parties purely for what they are. While we do not have direct evidence on why CSPs suffer from discrimination, these results appear to be consistent with theories of the regime divide in the region. The most plausible explanation is that the electorates of parties associated with the opposition to commu- nism still hold affective dislike for their former oppressors and wish to penalize them. Parties will presumably heed these preferences, because they would lose votes by doing otherwise. The implication is that scholars researching other new democra- cies may want to pay more attention to the coalition preferences of voters. It is in these countries that the affective feelings of voters toward particular parties are likely to be the strongest, and parties thus face considerable pressure to attend to these preferences.
  • 72. This research validates both the suggestion of coalition theorists that party identity may matter in coalition formation and the idea that vote-seeking plays an important role in parties’ decisions about coalitions. Neither idea is new, but both have been neglected in the quantitative study of coalition politics. Our results suggest that scholars should pay more attention to affective dislike between supporters of rival parties and the consequences this bias has for parties that, in addition to seeking office and policy outcomes, worry about their future electability. 25Coalition Formation in Eastern Europe We believe two extensions of this research to be especially compelling (in addition to the aforementioned need to analyze coalition formation using Martin and Stevenson’s approach). First, scholars might ask if CSPs affect other facets of coalition government, such as government duration and, most important, policy choices. Studies of Western Europe suggest that the composition of governments does affect policy, but this influence has yet to be shown in Eastern Europe. The second extension would be to investigate whether or not these legacies of the old regime matter in other new democracies. Are
  • 73. repre- sentatives of the old regime penalized more generally, or are our results specific to the postcommunist world? James N. Druckman ([email protected]) is Associate Professor of Political Science and Andrew Roberts ([email protected]) is Assistant Professor of Political Science, both at Northwestern University, 601 University Place, Evanston, IL 60208. NOTES We thank Michael Parkin for research assistance and Lanny Martin and the reviewers for helpful comments. Druckman acknowledges support from the University of Minnesota McKnight Land-Grant Professorship and from Northwestern University’s AT&T Research Scholar Funds. 1. Among the comparative works on the topic are Bozóki and Ishiyama 2002; Curry and Urban 2003; Evans and Whitefield 1995; Grzymala- Busse 1998, 2001, 2002a; Ishiyama 1995, 1996, 1997, 1998, 1999a, 1999b; Ishiyama and Bozóki 2001; Mahr and Nagle 1995; Moraski and Loewenberg 1999; Orenstein 1998; Waller 1995; and Ziblatt 1998. Many more articles focusing on individual CSPs could be cited. 2. This expectation is frequently exaggerated. Even the most repressive dicta- torships serve some constituency that might be expected to continue its support after a
  • 74. democratic transition. 3. Exceptions include Bunce 2002; Grzymala-Busse 2001, 2002b; and Ishiyama 1999c. In fact, Grzymala-Busse’s (2001) article considers the same issue as this article— the effect of the communist legacy on coalition formation. Our article extends her work by taking a large-N approach, allowing the inclusion of control variables, and looking at additional aspects of coalition formation. 4. Kitschelt et al. (1999, 65) define the regime divide as the phenomenon wherein “memories about old-regime performance, periodically updated by more recent events, affect people’s orientation toward the pre-democratic incumbents.” Grzymala-Busse (2001, 85) calls it “the depth and character of the persisting conflict between the successors to the pre-1989 Communist parties and the parties emerging from the Communist-era opposition.” 5. All of the successor parties considered here have proclaimed, rhetorically at least, support for the democratic process. 26 James N. Druckman and Andrew Roberts 6. Grzymala-Busse (2001) suggests an additional way, the desire of parties to build reputations. While we agree with this outlook, we believe that this desire works
  • 75. through the vote-seeking motivation that we emphasize, as Grzymala-Busse herself seems to suggest. 7. We would add the possibility that CSPs elicit distinctive dynamics because they behave differently than other parties, perhaps by retaining their authoritarian ways. We later discuss this possibility in more detail, but we do not find any confir- mation of it. It is worth noting that this expectation generates predictions that are the opposite of those suggested by the regime divide theory. 8. There are additional reasons why vote seeking might be particularly important in Eastern Europe. First, voters have punished incumbents quite heavily in the region. Vote losses in the double digits are the norm rather than the exception for sitting governments (Roberts 2006). Further, parties appear and disappear with great frequency in the region (Rose and Munro 2003). A single poor election result is often enough to push a party into oblivion. Parties thus have good reason to weigh care- fully the possibility of offending their electorates, even if they are tempted by the spoils of office and policy influence. 9. The Hungarian Socialist Party won 54% of the seats in this election and yet still entered a coalition with the second-place party, the Alliance of Free Democrats. 10. As we will discuss later, there is an active debate about
  • 76. whether formateurs are advantaged or disadvantaged in portfolio allocation (see Warwick and Druckman 2006). 11. We excluded caretaker governments, technocratic (nonpartisan) govern- ments, and single-party governments. We also included only those governments that passed an investiture vote (if one was held). A government ends and another one begins when an election occurs, the head of government changes, the party member- ship of the government changes, or the government resigns (Warwick and Druckman 2001, 633). Data details are available from the authors. 12. Following all other work on the topic, we did not count the puppet allies of the communist party, such as the Polish Peasants’ Party. Citizens surely realized that these parties did not exercise any power, and thus the parties should not have been blamed for the regime’s crimes. 13. Martin and Stevenson (2001) have found that it is not size per se that affects entry into government but rather formateur status. Parties that are formateurs are more likely to enter government. Because all of the formateurs in our dataset entered government (that is, we coded only successful formateurs, for the purposes of portfolio allocation), we cannot test this possibility here. Since, however, size is related to formateur status—larger parties are more likely to be
  • 77. formateurs—this omission should not bias our results. Indeed, in our dataset, the average seat share of formateurs is 37% compared to 11% for nonformateurs. 14. We conducted several robustness checks on these results. First, since our data include different numbers of coalitions in each country (e.g., one in Serbia, nine in Poland), some countries may influence the results more than others. We thus reran our regressions using country weights, and we found no substantive difference from the results reported in Table 3. Second, participation by the same parties in the same coalition-formation episode is not independent. We thus ran specifications that used clustering on the formation episode and robust standard errors. Again, we found no 27Coalition Formation in Eastern Europe difference in results using this specification. Third, we added dummies for parties on the far right—nationalist and ultra-rightist parties. Again, the CSP variable remains highly significant, although we did find that nationalists are penalized as well. Strangely, ultra-rightist parties are not treated differently. Finally, we included an interaction term between CSP and seat share, as the impact of CSP status may depend on seat share. The interaction term is marginally significant at first (as CSPs grow
  • 78. larger, they are advantaged relative to other parties), but the significant effect disappears when we control for incumbency. The main effect of CSPs remains, despite these controls. 15. Details, including standard errors, are available from the authors. 16. There are no cases of multiple CSPs in governme nt. We also conducted regression analyses that control for the number of parties in the coalition, the number of parties in the legislature, and the types of parties in the coalition. Even with the inclusion of these controls, the presence of a CSP still makes a coalition significantly more likely to be oversized. 17. The one exception was the first Slovenian government, which was neither a minority nor a near-unity coalition, although it did control 68% of the legislative seats. We also note that, among majority governments, 46.5% (87/187) of non-CSPs were pivotal, compared to 75% (22/29) of CSPs (z = 2.86, p < .01 for a two-tailed difference-of-proportions test). 18. Note two other points. First, CSPs are not more likely to be pivot parties when we control for party size. This result is of limited interest, however, because it simply reveals the tautology that larger parties are more likely than smaller parties to be pivotal. The fact is that when such larger parties are CSPs,
  • 79. they are included, presumably because of their pivotal status. In other cases, CSPs tend not be included, whereas other parties are. Second, we found that, in many cases, a CSP in govern- ment is the only pivotal party. Among majority coalitions, only 13% (11/87) of non- CSPs are the single pivotal party in a coalition. The analogous figure for CSPs is 59% (13/22). 19. There is typically some deviation from proportionality in the form of a small-party bias, such that small parties receive a bit more than their share and large parties, including the formateurs, receive less (see Warwick and Druckman 2001, 2006). 20. We did not include controls for ideology or incumbency in this analysis. Prior work has not considered these variables, and we do not see any reason why they should affect portfolio allocation. Furthermore, ideology controls would suffer from multicollinearity with the CSP variable, as the ideologies of CSPs that enter government are much more limited than the types that receive legislative seats. When we regress the CSP interaction on the country dummy interactions, the R2 is .89. 21. As in the analysis of participation, we also ran regressions with country weights to account for the fact that some countries have more coalitions than others.
  • 80. These weights do not affect the substantive results. 22. Ideal would be comparative public opinion data on attitudes toward CSPs as acceptable members of government. We would be particularly interested in the intensity of these feelings, as that would give us an idea of whether or not there would be electoral punishment for forming coalitions with CSPs. We did find data from the New Democracies Barometer on attitudes toward the old regime in general 28 James N. Druckman and Andrew Roberts (Rose and Haerpfer 1996). These data indicate that advanced countries are slightly more likely to view the communist regime negatively, but the differences are not large. 23. In other work, we have found that the formateur effect differs between the two groups of countries; this finding does not have implications for CSPs per se, however (see Druckman and Roberts 2005). REFERENCES Andrews, Josephine. 2002. When Majorities Fail: The Russian Parliament, 1990– 1993. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Ansolabehere, Stephen, James M. Snyder, Jr., Aaron B. Strauss,
  • 81. and Michael M. Ting. 2005. “Voting Weights and Formateur Advantages in the Formation of Coali- tion Governments.” American Journal of Political Science 49: 550–63. Armingeon, Klaus, and Romana Careja. 2004. Comparative Data Set for 28 Post- Communist Countries, 1989–2004. Bern, Switzerland: Institute of Political Science, University of Berne. Baron, David, and John Ferejohn. 1989. “Bargaining in Legislatures.” American Political Science Review 83: 1181–1206. Blondel, Jean, and Ferdinand Müller-Rommel, eds. 2001. Cabinets in Eastern Europe. New York: Palgrave. Bozóki, András, and John T. Ishiyama, eds. 2002. The Communist Successor Parties of Central and Eastern Europe. Armonk, NY: M.E. Sharpe. Browne, Eric, and Mark Franklin. 1973. “Aspects of Coalition Payoffs in European Parliamentary Democracies.” American Political Science Review 67: 453–69. Bunce, Valerie. 2002. “The Return of the Left and Democratic Consolidation in Poland and Hungary.” In The Communist Successor Parties of Central and Eastern Europe, ed. András Bozóki and John T. Ishiyama. Armonk, NY: M.E. Sharpe.
  • 82. Curry, Jane Leftwich, and Joan Urban, eds. 2003. The Left Transformed in Postcommunist Societies: The Cases of East-Central Europe, Russia, and Ukraine. Lanham, MD: Rowan and Littlefield. De Winter, Lieven. 1995. “The Role of Parliament in Government Formation and Resignation.” In Parliaments and Majority Rule in Western Europe, ed. Herbert Doring. Frankfurt: Campus Verlag. Dodd, Lawrence C. 1976. Coalitions in Parliamentary Government. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. Druckman, James N., and Andrew Roberts. 2005. “Context and Coalition Bargaining: Comparing Portfolio Allocation in Eastern and Western Europe.” Party Politics 11: 535–55. Druckman, James N., and Andrew Roberts. N.d. “Measuring Portfolio Salience in Eastern European Parliamentary Democracies.” European Journal of Political Research. Forthcoming. Druckman, James N., and Michael F. Thies. 2002. “The Importance of Concurrence: The Impact of Bicameralism on Government Formation and Duration.” American Journal of Political Science 46: 760–71.
  • 83. 29Coalition Formation in Eastern Europe Evans, Geoffrey, and Stephen Whitefield. 1995. “Economic Ideology and Political Success: Communist Successor Parties in the Czech Republic, Slovakia and Hungary Compared.” Party Politics 1: 565–78. Gamson, William A. 1961. “A Theory of Coalition Formation.” American Sociological Review 26: 373–82. Grzymala-Busse, Anna. 1998. “Reform Efforts in the Czech and Slovak Communist Parties and Their Successors, 1988–1993.” East European Politics and Societies 12: 442–71. Grzymala-Busse, Anna. 2001. “Coalition Formation and the Regime Divide in New Democracies: East Central Europe.” Comparative Politics 34: 85–104. Grzymala-Busse, Anna. 2002a. Redeeming the Communist Past: The Regeneration of Communist Successor Parties in East Central Europe. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Grzymala-Busse, Anna. 2002b. “The Effects of Communist Party Transformation on the Institutionalization of Party Systems.” In The Communist Successor Parties of Central and Eastern Europe, ed. András Bozóki and John T. Ishiyama. Armonk, NY: M.E. Sharpe.
  • 84. Harrington, Joseph. 1990. “The Power of the Proposal Maker in a Model of Endog- enous Agenda Formation.” Public Choice 64: 1–20. Huber, John D. 1996. “The Vote of Confidence in Parliamentary Democracies.” American Political Science Review 90: 269–82. Ishiyama, John. 1995. “Communist Parties in Transition: Structures, Leaders, and Processes of Democratization in Eastern Europe.” Comparative Politics 27: 147–66. Ishiyama, John. 1996. “Red Phoenix? The Communist Party in Post-Soviet Russian Politics.” Party Politics 2: 147–75. Ishiyama, John. 1997. “The Sickle or the Rose?: Previous Regime Types and the Evolution of the Ex-Communist Parties in Post-Communist Politics.” Comparative Political Studies 30: 299–330. Ishiyama, John. 1998. “Red versus Expert: Candidate Recruitment and Communist Party Adaptation in Post Soviet Politics.” Party Politics 4: 297– 318. Ishiyama, John. 1999a. “The Communist Successor Parties and Party Organizational Development in Post-Communist Politics.” Political Research Quarterly 53: 87–112.
  • 85. Ishiyama, John. 1999b. Communist Successor Parties in Post- Communist Politics. Carmack, NY: Nova Science. Ishiyama, John. 1999c. “Sickles into Roses: The Communist Successor Parties and Demo- cratic Consolidation in Comparative Perspective.” Democratization 6: 52–73. Ishiyama, John, and András Bozóki. 2001. “Adaptation and Change: Characterizing the Survival Strategies of Communist Successor Parties.” Journal of Communist Studies and Transition Politics 17: 32–51. Keesing’s Contemporary Archives. 1990–2003. London: Keesing’s Publications. King, Charles. 2000. “Post-Postcommunism: Transition, Comparison, and the End of Eastern Europe.” World Politics 53: 143–72. Kitschelt, Herbert, Zdenka Mansfeldova, Radoslaw Markowski, and Gabor Toka. 1999. Post-Communist Party Systems: Competition, Representation, and Inter-Party Cooperation. New York: Cambridge University Press. 30 James N. Druckman and Andrew Roberts Klingemann, Hans-Dieter, Richard I. Hofferbert, and Ian Budge. 1994. Parties, Policies, and Democracy. Boulder, CO: Westview.
  • 86. Kreuzer, Marcus, and Vello Pettai. 2003. “Patterns of Political Instability: Affiliation Patterns of Politicians and Voters in Post-Communist Estonia, Latvia, and Lithuania.” Studies in Comparative International Development 38: 76–98. Lane, Jan-Erik, David McKay, and Kenneth Newton. 1997. Political Data Handbook. 2d ed. Oxford: Oxford University Press. Laver, Michael. 1998. “Models of Government Formation.” Annual Review of Political Science 1: 1–25. Laver, Michael, and Norman Schofield. 1990. Multiparty Government: The Politics of Coalition in Europe. Oxford: Oxford University Press. Laver, Michael, and Kenneth Shepsle. 1996. Making and Breaking Governments. New York: Cambridge University Press. Lijphart, Arend. 1999. Patterns of Democracy: Majoritarian and Consensus Forms in 36 Democracies. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press. Mahr, Allison, and John Nagle. 1995. “Resurrection of the Successor Parties and Democratization in East-Central Europe.” Communist and Post- Communist Studies 28: 393–409. Martin, Lanny W., and Randolph T. Stevenson. 2001. “Government Formation in Parliamentary Democracies.” American Journal of Political
  • 87. Science 45: 33–50. Mershon, Carol. 1994. “Expectations and Informal Rules in Coalition Formation.” Comparative Political Studies 27: 40–79. Mershon, Carol. 1996. “The Costs of Coalition: Coalition Theories and Italian Governments.” American Political Science Review 90: 534–54. Mershon, Carol. 2002. The Costs of Coalition. Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press. Moraski, Bryon, and Gerhard Loewenberg. 1999. “The Effect of Legal Thresholds on the Revival of Former Communist Parties in East-Central Europe.” Journal of Politics 61: 151–70. Morelli, Massimo. 1999. “Demand Competition and Policy Compromise in Legisla- tive Bargaining.” American Political Science Review 93: 809– 20. Orenstein, Mitchell. 1998. “A Genealogy of Communist Successor Parties in East- Central Europe and the Determinants of their Success.” East European Politics and Societies 12: 472–99. Riker, William. 1962. The Theory of Political Coalitions. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press. Roberts, Andrew. 2006. “Hyperaccountability: Economic Voting in Eastern Europe.”
  • 88. Northwestern University. Typescript. Rose, Richard, and Christian Haerpfer. 1996. “Change and Stability in the New Democ- racies Barometer.” University of Strathclyde: Center for the Study of Public Policy. Rose, Richard, and Neil Munro. 2003. Elections and Parties in New European Democracies. Washington, DC: CQ. Schofield, Norman, and Michael Laver. 1985. “Bargaining Theory and Portfolio Pay- offs in European Coalition Governments, 1945–83.” British Journal of Political Science 15: 143–64. Shabad, Goldie, and Kazimierz M. Slomczynski. 2004. “Inter - party Mobility among Parliamentary Candidates in Post-Communist East Central Europe.” Party Politics 10: 151–76. 31Coalition Formation in Eastern Europe Strøm, Kaare. 1990a. “A Behavioral Theory of Competitive Parties.” American Journal of Political Science 34: 565–98. Strøm, Kaare. 1990b. Minority Government and Majority Rule. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Strøm, Kaare, Ian Budge, and Michael Laver. 1994.
  • 89. “Constraints on Government Formation in Parliamentary Democracies.” American Journal of Political Sci- ence 38: 303–35. Tomz, Michael, Jason Wittenberg, and Gary King. 1999. “Clarify.” Version 1.2.1 http://gking.harvard.edu (June 1, 1999). Vachudova, Milada Anna, and Tim Snyder. 1997. “Are Transitions Transitory? Two Types of Political Change in Eastern Europe since 1989.” East European Politics and Societies 11: 1–35. Volden, Craig, and Clifford J. Carrubba. 2004. “The Formation of Oversized Coali- tions in Parliamentary Democracies.” American Journal of Political Science 48: 521–37. Waller, Michael. 1995. “Adaptation of the Former Communist Parties of East-Central Europe. A Case of Democratization?” Party Politics 1: 373–90. Warwick, Paul V., and James N. Druckman. 2001. “Portfolio Salience and the Propor- tionality of Payoffs in Coalition Governments.” British Journal of Political Science 31: 627–49. Warwick, Paul V., and James N. Druckman. 2006. “The Paradox of Portfolio Alloca- tion: An Investigation into the Nature of a Very Strong but Puzzling Relation- ship.” European Journal of Political Research 45: 635–65.
  • 90. Ziblatt, Daniel F. 1998. “The Adaptation of Ex-Communist Parties to Post-Communist East Central Europe: A Comparative Study of the East German and Hungarian Ex-Communist Parties.” Communist and Post Communist Studies 31: 119–37. 32 James N. Druckman and Andrew Roberts << /ASCII85EncodePages false /AllowTransparency false /AutoPositionEPSFiles true /AutoRotatePages /None /Binding /Left /CalGrayProfile (Gray Gamma 2.2) /CalRGBProfile (Adobe RGB 0501998051) /CalCMYKProfile (U.S. Web Coated 050SWOP051 v2) /sRGBProfile (sRGB IEC61966-2.1) /CannotEmbedFontPolicy /Error /CompatibilityLevel 1.3 /CompressObjects /Off /CompressPages true /ConvertImagesToIndexed true /PassThroughJPEGImages true /CreateJDFFile false /CreateJobTicket false /DefaultRenderingIntent /Default /DetectBlends true /DetectCurves 0.1000 /ColorConversionStrategy /LeaveColorUnchanged /DoThumbnails false /EmbedAllFonts true
  • 91. /EmbedOpenType false /ParseICCProfilesInComments true /EmbedJobOptions true /DSCReportingLevel 0 /EmitDSCWarnings false /EndPage -1 /ImageMemory 1048576 /LockDistillerParams true /MaxSubsetPct 100 /Optimize true /OPM 1 /ParseDSCComments true /ParseDSCCommentsForDocInfo true /PreserveCopyPage false /PreserveDICMYKValues true /PreserveEPSInfo true /PreserveFlatness false /PreserveHalftoneInfo false /PreserveOPIComments false /PreserveOverprintSettings true /StartPage 1 /SubsetFonts false /TransferFunctionInfo /Apply /UCRandBGInfo /Remove /UsePrologue false /ColorSettingsFile (Color Management Off) /AlwaysEmbed [ true /Courier /Courier-Bold /Courier-BoldOblique /Courier-Oblique /Helvetica /Helvetica-Bold /Helvetica-BoldOblique /Helvetica-Oblique /Symbol
  • 92. /Times-Bold /Times-BoldItalic /Times-Italic /Times-Roman /ZapfDingbats ] /NeverEmbed [ true ] /AntiAliasColorImages false /CropColorImages false /ColorImageMinResolution 266 /ColorImageMinResolutionPolicy /Warning /DownsampleColorImages false /ColorImageDownsampleType /None /ColorImageResolution 300 /ColorImageDepth -1 /ColorImageMinDownsampleDepth 1 /ColorImageDownsampleThreshold 1.50000 /EncodeColorImages true /ColorImageFilter /DCTEncode /AutoFilterColorImages true /ColorImageAutoFilterStrategy /JPEG /ColorACSImageDict << /QFactor 0.15 /HSamples [1 1 1 1] /VSamples [1 1 1 1] >> /ColorImageDict << /QFactor 0.15 /HSamples [1 1 1 1] /VSamples [1 1 1 1] >> /JPEG2000ColorACSImageDict << /TileWidth 256 /TileHeight 256 /Quality 30 >> /JPEG2000ColorImageDict <<
  • 93. /TileWidth 256 /TileHeight 256 /Quality 30 >> /AntiAliasGrayImages false /CropGrayImages false /GrayImageMinResolution 266 /GrayImageMinResolutionPolicy /Warning /DownsampleGrayImages false /GrayImageDownsampleType /None /GrayImageResolution 300 /GrayImageDepth -1 /GrayImageMinDownsampleDepth 2 /GrayImageDownsampleThreshold 1.50000 /EncodeGrayImages true /GrayImageFilter /DCTEncode /AutoFilterGrayImages true /GrayImageAutoFilterStrategy /JPEG /GrayACSImageDict << /QFactor 0.15 /HSamples [1 1 1 1] /VSamples [1 1 1 1] >> /GrayImageDict << /QFactor 0.15 /HSamples [1 1 1 1] /VSamples [1 1 1 1] >> /JPEG2000GrayACSImageDict << /TileWidth 256 /TileHeight 256 /Quality 30 >> /JPEG2000GrayImageDict << /TileWidth 256 /TileHeight 256 /Quality 30 >>
  • 94. /AntiAliasMonoImages false /CropMonoImages false /MonoImageMinResolution 900 /MonoImageMinResolutionPolicy /Warning /DownsampleMonoImages false /MonoImageDownsampleType /None /MonoImageResolution 1200 /MonoImageDepth -1 /MonoImageDownsampleThreshold 1.50000 /EncodeMonoImages true /MonoImageFilter /CCITTFaxEncode /MonoImageDict << /K -1 >> /AllowPSXObjects false /CheckCompliance [ /None ] /PDFX1aCheck false /PDFX3Check false /PDFXCompliantPDFOnly false /PDFXNoTrimBoxError true /PDFXTrimBoxToMediaBoxOffset [ 0.00000 0.00000 0.00000 0.00000 ] /PDFXSetBleedBoxToMediaBox true /PDFXBleedBoxToTrimBoxOffset [ 0.00000 0.00000 0.00000 0.00000 ] /PDFXOutputIntentProfile (None)
  • 95. /PDFXOutputConditionIdentifier () /PDFXOutputCondition () /PDFXRegistryName () /PDFXTrapped /False /Description << /CHS <FEFF4f7f75288fd94e9b8bbe5b9a521b5efa76840020005000440 04600206587686353ef901a8fc7684c976262535370673a548c002 000700072006f006f00660065007200208fdb884c9ad88d2891cf6 2535370300260a853ef4ee54f7f75280020004100630072006f006 2006100740020548c002000410064006f00620065002000520065 006100640065007200200035002e003000204ee553ca66f49ad87 248672c676562535f00521b5efa76840020005000440046002065 8768633002> /CHT <FEFF4f7f752890194e9b8a2d7f6e5efa7acb76840020004100640 06f006200650020005000440046002065874ef653ef5728684c976 2537088686a5f548c002000700072006f006f00660065007200204 e0a73725f979ad854c18cea7684521753706548679c300260a853e f4ee54f7f75280020004100630072006f0062006100740020548c0 02000410064006f00620065002000520065006100640065007200 200035002e003000204ee553ca66f49ad87248672c4f86958b555f 5df25efa7acb76840020005000440046002065874ef63002> /DAN <FEFF004200720075006700200069006e0064007300740069006 c006c0069006e006700650072006e0065002000740069006c0020 006100740020006f0070007200650074007400650020004100640 06f006200650020005000440046002d0064006f006b0075006d00 65006e007400650072002000740069006c0020006b00760061006 c00690074006500740073007500640073006b007200690076006e 0069006e006700200065006c006c006500720020006b006f00720 0720065006b007400750072006c00e60073006e0069006e006700 2e0020004400650020006f0070007200650074007400650064006 50020005000440046002d0064006f006b0075006d0065006e0074 006500720020006b0061006e002000e50062006e0065007300200
  • 96. 0690020004100630072006f00620061007400200065006c006c00 6500720020004100630072006f006200610074002000520065006 100640065007200200035002e00300020006f00670020006e0079 006500720065002e> /DEU <FEFF00560065007200770065006e00640065006e00200053006 90065002000640069006500730065002000450069006e00730074 0065006c006c0075006e00670065006e0020007a0075006d00200 0450072007300740065006c006c0065006e00200076006f006e00 2000410064006f006200650020005000440046002d0044006f006 b0075006d0065006e00740065006e002c00200076006f006e0020 00640065006e0065006e002000530069006500200068006f00630 06800770065007200740069006700650020004400720075006300 6b006500200061007500660020004400650073006b0074006f007 0002d0044007200750063006b00650072006e00200075006e0064 002000500072006f006f0066002d00470065007200e4007400650 06e002000650072007a0065007500670065006e0020006d00f600 63006800740065006e002e002000450072007300740065006c006 c007400650020005000440046002d0044006f006b0075006d0065 006e007400650020006b00f6006e006e0065006e0020006d00690 0740020004100630072006f00620061007400200075006e006400 2000410064006f006200650020005200650061006400650072002 00035002e00300020006f0064006500720020006800f600680065 007200200067006500f600660066006e006500740020007700650 07200640065006e002e> /ESP <FEFF005500740069006c0069006300650020006500730074006 100200063006f006e0066006900670075007200610063006900f3 006e0020007000610072006100200063007200650061007200200 064006f00630075006d0065006e0074006f007300200064006500 2000410064006f006200650020005000440046002000700061007 2006100200063006f006e00730065006700750069007200200069 006d0070007200650073006900f3006e002000640065002000630 061006c006900640061006400200065006e00200069006d007000 7200650073006f007200610073002000640065002000650073006 3007200690074006f00720069006f002000790020006800650072
  • 97. 00720061006d00690065006e00740061007300200064006500200 063006f00720072006500630063006900f3006e002e0020005300 65002000700075006500640065006e00200061006200720069007 200200064006f00630075006d0065006e0074006f007300200050 00440046002000630072006500610064006f007300200063006f0 06e0020004100630072006f006200610074002c00200041006400 6f00620065002000520065006100640065007200200035002e003 000200079002000760065007200730069006f006e006500730020 0070006f00730074006500720069006f007200650073002e> /FRA <FEFF005500740069006c006900730065007a002000630065007 30020006f007000740069006f006e00730020006100660069006e 00200064006500200063007200e90065007200200064006500730 0200064006f00630075006d0065006e0074007300200041006400 6f00620065002000500044004600200070006f007500720020006 400650073002000e9007000720065007500760065007300200065 0074002000640065007300200069006d007000720065007300730 069006f006e007300200064006500200068006100750074006500 20007100750061006c0069007400e900200073007500720020006 40065007300200069006d007000720069006d0061006e00740065 00730020006400650020006200750072006500610075002e00200 04c0065007300200064006f00630075006d0065006e0074007300 2000500044004600200063007200e900e90073002000700065007 500760065006e0074002000ea0074007200650020006f00750076 0065007200740073002000640061006e007300200041006300720 06f006200610074002c002000610069006e007300690020007100 75002700410064006f00620065002000520065006100640065007 200200035002e0030002000650074002000760065007200730069 006f006e007300200075006c007400e9007200690065007500720 0650073002e> /ITA <FEFF005500740069006c0069007a007a0061007200650020007 10075006500730074006500200069006d0070006f007300740061 007a0069006f006e0069002000700065007200200063007200650 0610072006500200064006f00630075006d0065006e0074006900 2000410064006f006200650020005000440046002000700065007
  • 98. 200200075006e00610020007300740061006d0070006100200064 00690020007100750061006c0069007400e000200073007500200 07300740061006d00700061006e00740069002000650020007000 72006f006f0066006500720020006400650073006b0074006f007 0002e0020004900200064006f00630075006d0065006e00740069 00200050004400460020006300720065006100740069002000700 06f00730073006f006e006f0020006500730073006500720065002 000610070006500720074006900200063006f006e002000410063 0072006f00620061007400200065002000410064006f006200650 02000520065006100640065007200200035002e00300020006500 2000760065007200730069006f006e00690020007300750063006 3006500730073006900760065002e> /JPN <FEFF9ad854c18cea51fa529b7528002000410064006f00620065 00200050004400460020658766f8306e4f5c6210306b4f7f752830 57307e30593002537052376642306e753b8cea309267005927965 0306b4fdd306430533068304c3067304d307e3059300230c730b9 30af30c830c330d730d730ea30f330bf3067306e53705237307e30 5f306f30d730eb30fc30d57528306b9069305730663044307e3059 30023053306e8a2d5b9a30674f5c62103055308c305f0020005000 440046002030d530a130a430eb306f3001004100630072006f006 2006100740020304a30883073002000410064006f006200650020 00520065006100640065007200200035002e003000204ee5964d3 067958b304f30533068304c3067304d307e30593002> /KOR <FEFFc7740020c124c815c7440020c0acc6a9d558c5ec0020b370 c2a4d06cd0d10020d504b9b0d1300020bc0f0020ad50c815ae30c5 d0c11c0020ace0d488c9c8b85c0020c778c1c4d560002000410064 006f0062006500200050004400460020bb38c11cb97c0020c791c 131d569b2c8b2e4002e0020c774b807ac8c0020c791c131b41c002 00050004400460020bb38c11cb2940020004100630072006f0062 006100740020bc0f002000410064006f006200650020005200650 06100640065007200200035002e00300020c774c0c1c5d0c11c00 20c5f40020c2180020c788c2b5b2c8b2e4002e> /NLD (Gebruik deze instellingen om Adobe PDF-documenten te maken voor kwaliteitsafdrukken op desktopprinters en
  • 99. proofers. De gemaakte PDF-documenten kunnen worden geopend met Acrobat en Adobe Reader 5.0 en hoger.) /NOR <FEFF004200720075006b0020006400690073007300650020006 9006e006e007300740069006c006c0069006e00670065006e0065 002000740069006c002000e50020006f007000700072006500740 0740065002000410064006f006200650020005000440046002d00 64006f006b0075006d0065006e00740065007200200066006f007 20020007500740073006b00720069006600740020006100760020 006800f800790020006b00760061006c006900740065007400200 07000e500200062006f007200640073006b007200690076006500 7200200065006c006c00650072002000700072006f006f0066006 50072002e0020005000440046002d0064006f006b0075006d0065 006e00740065006e00650020006b0061006e002000e50070006e0 0650073002000690020004100630072006f006200610074002000 65006c006c00650072002000410064006f0062006500200052006 5006100640065007200200035002e003000200065006c006c0065 0072002000730065006e006500720065002e> /PTB <FEFF005500740069006c0069007a00650020006500730073006 1007300200063006f006e00660069006700750072006100e700f5 0065007300200064006500200066006f0072006d0061002000610 0200063007200690061007200200064006f00630075006d006500 6e0074006f0073002000410064006f00620065002000500044004 60020007000610072006100200069006d00700072006500730073 00f5006500730020006400650020007100750061006c006900640 0610064006500200065006d00200069006d007000720065007300 73006f0072006100730020006400650073006b0074006f0070002 0006500200064006900730070006f00730069007400690076006f 0073002000640065002000700072006f00760061002e0020004f0 07300200064006f00630075006d0065006e0074006f0073002000 5000440046002000630072006900610064006f007300200070006 f00640065006d0020007300650072002000610062006500720074 006f007300200063006f006d0020006f0020004100630072006f00 6200610074002000650020006f002000410064006f00620065002 000520065006100640065007200200035002e0030002000650020
  • 100. 007600650072007300f50065007300200070006f0073007400650 0720069006f007200650073002e> /SUO <FEFF004b00e40079007400e40020006e00e40069007400e4002 000610073006500740075006b007300690061002c0020006b0075 006e0020006c0075006f0074002000410064006f0062006500200 050004400460020002d0064006f006b0075006d0065006e007400 740065006a00610020006c0061006100640075006b00610073007 4006100200074007900f6007000f60079007400e400740075006c 006f0073007400750073007400610020006a00610020007600650 064006f0073007400750073007400610020007600610072007400 65006e002e00200020004c0075006f00640075007400200050004 40046002d0064006f006b0075006d0065006e0074006900740020 0076006f0069006400610061006e0020006100760061007400610 020004100630072006f0062006100740069006c006c0061002000 6a0061002000410064006f0062006500200052006500610064006 5007200200035002e0030003a006c006c00610020006a00610020 0075007500640065006d006d0069006c006c0061002e> /SVE <FEFF0041006e007600e4006e00640020006400650020006800e 4007200200069006e0073007400e4006c006c006e0069006e0067 00610072006e00610020006f006d0020006400750020007600690 06c006c00200073006b006100700061002000410064006f006200 650020005000440046002d0064006f006b0075006d0065006e007 40020006600f600720020006b00760061006c0069007400650074 0073007500740073006b007200690066007400650072002000700 0e5002000760061006e006c00690067006100200073006b007200 6900760061007200650020006f006300680020006600f60072002 0006b006f007200720065006b007400750072002e002000200053 006b006100700061006400650020005000440046002d0064006f0 06b0075006d0065006e00740020006b0061006e002000f6007000 70006e00610073002000690020004100630072006f00620061007 40020006f00630068002000410064006f00620065002000520065 006100640065007200200035002e00300020006f0063006800200 0730065006e006100720065002e> /ENU (Use these settings to create Adobe PDF documents for
  • 101. quality printing on desktop printers and proofers. Created PDF documents can be opened with Acrobat and Adobe Reader 5.0 and later.) >> /Namespace [ (Adobe) (Common) (1.0) ] /OtherNamespaces [ << /AsReaderSpreads false /CropImagesToFrames false /ErrorControl /WarnAndContinue /FlattenerIgnoreSpreadOverrides true /IncludeGuidesGrids false /IncludeNonPrinting false /IncludeSlug false /Namespace [ (Adobe) (InDesign) (4.0) ] /OmitPlacedBitmaps false /OmitPlacedEPS false /OmitPlacedPDF false /SimulateOverprint /Legacy >> << /AddBleedMarks false /AddColorBars false /AddCropMarks true /AddPageInfo false /AddRegMarks false /BleedOffset [ 9
  • 102. 9 9 9 ] /ConvertColors /NoConversion /DestinationProfileName () /DestinationProfileSelector /NA /Downsample16BitImages true /FlattenerPreset << /ClipComplexRegions true /ConvertStrokesToOutlines false /ConvertTextToOutlines false /GradientResolution 300 /LineArtTextResolution 1200 /PresetName ([High Resolution]) /PresetSelector /HighResolution /RasterVectorBalance 1 >> /FormElements false /GenerateStructure false /IncludeBookmarks false /IncludeHyperlinks false /IncludeInteractive false /IncludeLayers false /IncludeProfiles false /MarksOffset 12 /MarksWeight 0.125000 /MultimediaHandling /UseObjectSettings /Namespace [ (Adobe) (CreativeSuite) (2.0) ] /PDFXOutputIntentProfileSelector /NA /PageMarksFile /RomanDefault /PreserveEditing true
  • 103. /UntaggedCMYKHandling /LeaveUntagged /UntaggedRGBHandling /LeaveUntagged /UseDocumentBleed false >> << /AllowImageBreaks true /AllowTableBreaks true /ExpandPage false /HonorBaseURL true /HonorRolloverEffect false /IgnoreHTMLPageBreaks false /IncludeHeaderFooter false /MarginOffset [ 0 0 0 0 ] /MetadataAuthor () /MetadataKeywords () /MetadataSubject () /MetadataTitle () /MetricPageSize [ 0 0 ] /MetricUnit /inch /MobileCompatible 0 /Namespace [ (Adobe) (GoLive) (8.0) ] /OpenZoomToHTMLFontSize false /PageOrientation /Portrait /RemoveBackground false
  • 104. /ShrinkContent true /TreatColorsAs /MainMonitorColors /UseEmbeddedProfiles false /UseHTMLTitleAsMetadata true >> ] >> setdistillerparams << /HWResolution [2400 2400] /PageSize [612.000 792.000] >> setpagedevice Counseling Disposition Reflection Worksheet Directions: Review the dispositions document and select three dispositions that you currently meet. Complete the chart by listing the dispositions met as well as a description of how you meet the disposition. Include a citation and paraphrase the definition. Please note: you do not need to be actively practicing to complete this worksheet. Disposition and Definition Description of how the disposition is met (75-100 words) 1. 2. 3.
  • 105. Directions: Now that you have identified dispositions that you currently meet, review the disposition document again and consider any dispositions that you do not meet. Complete the chart below by adding the two dispositions you do not meet as well as a preliminary plan in regards to how you plan to improve the identified dispositions. Disposition and Definition Description of how you plan to improve the disposition (75-100 words) 1. 2. © 2016. Grand Canyon University. All Rights Reserved. © 2014. Grand Canyon University. All Rights Reserved.