SlideShare a Scribd company logo
1 of 254
12/28/2021
1
Chapter Two: Defining Crimes and
Measuring Criminal Behavior
-Slides and data in this outline are from Adler, Mueller, and
Laufer (2007, 2013,
2018 & 2022); Siegel (2015); and modified by Manning (2007,
2013, 2015, 2018
& 2022).
Scared Straight Program – 1978 Rahway Max Prison
-Politically motivated –fit the get tough on crime bill
-Three year post experiment study shows evidence must be
evidence based
-Criminologists embrace a systematic empirical study of the
nature and extent of crime.
Example of successful criminology research based policy:
-Domestic violence research between 1981-82 shows police
counseling and temporary separation was
not effective.
-Now there are more mandatory arrest being made.
7 Basic Requirements for an Act to be a Crime
Defense must prove failure of a basic requirement
• 1. The act requirement – mind & Body
• Conscious act not an unconscious act or reaction
• Not a status or condition
• 2. The legality requirement – prohibited by law
• Thoughts without action – no crime
• Choosing to not fill out sex registration forms – is a crime
• Good Samaritan?
• 3. The harm requirement
• 4. The causation requirement
• Behavior in question caused the harm – not a 3rd party
• 5. The mens rea requirement (guilty mind)
• 6. The concurrence requirement
• Must be a criminal act with criminal intent (Ex: striker – rock
–window)
• Exceptions – felony murder
• 7. The punishment requirement – its must already exist
12/28/2021
2
Criminal defense negates basic ingredients of
crime.
• Crime – must be known to the police
• Not all crimes reported are cleared
• DA will not always prosecute
• Defense negation of crime elements examples:
• Insanity defense; legality requirement lacking; duress, self-
defense.
• State tries cases on behalf of the state
• Victims can file civil law suits for pain and suffering
Typologies of Crime
• The French created the following three categories accepted
worldwide
• Felonies - severe
• Misdemeanors – minor
• Violation - fines
• As Criminologist we will also focus on the following
• Violent crime
• Crimes against property
• White collar and corporate crime
• Drug, alcohol and sex-related crime
12/28/2021
3
Reasons for Measuring Crime
• Researchers collect and analyze data to test theories about
why
people commit crime.
• Researchers and criminal justice agencies need to enhance
their
knowledge of the characteristics of various types of offenses.
• Criminal justice agencies depend on certain information to
facilitate
daily operations and anticipate future needs.
The Research Process
• Topic – research question
• Theory: is a set of principles that explain how 2 or more
phenomena
are related
• May choose to use a hypothesis or not.
• Methodology (qualitative vs. quantitative)
• Will you use secondary data or primary data
• Analysis
• What did you do, findings, discussions and conclusions
12/28/2021
4
Exploring and defining the Thesis Process
• Abstract
• Introduction
• Methodology – Analysis of secondary data
• Theory
• Methodology – Exploration of primary data
• Findings
• Discussion and Conclusions
• References
Methodologies used to Collect Primary Data on Crime
• 1. Survey Research
• And interviews
• 2. Experiments
• 3. Observation
• 4. Participant Observation
• 5. Case Studies
12/28/2021
5
Surveys
and interviews explored
• The systematic collection of respondents’ answers to questions
asked
in questionnaires or interviews.
• Population
• Sample
• Random Sample
Experiments
• An investigator introduces a change into a process and makes
measurements or observations in order to evaluate the effects of
the
change.
• Variables:
• Independent Variable A causes Dependent Variable B to
Change
• Control Group
• Pretest and post test
12/28/2021
6
Participant and Non-Participant Observation
• In participant observation the researcher may join and
participate in
the activities of the group being studied.
• In observational research the researcher observes the group
being
studies but is not a participant in the activities.
• This process may be used to study criminals, prisoners,
prosecutors,
or police officers.
Case Studies
• A case study is an analysis of all pertinent aspects of one unit
of study,
such as an individual, an institution, a group or a community.
• Sources of information may be life histories, biographies,
diaries,
journals, letters, and other records.
• Edwin Sutherlands “The Professional Thief”
12/28/2021
7
Ethics and Research in Criminology
researcher responsibilities studying “vulnerable populations”
• Should the results of interviews be published?
• If the research does not disclose names could the participant
be
obstructing justice?
• Is there confidentiality for a criminal suspect?
• Does a researcher have to turn over his/her files if requested
by the police
or court?
• Should criminologists be immune from prosecution?
• Is it possible to develop a technique that can ensure against
identification
of the subjects in a file?
• Informed consent, avoid invasion of privacy
• Do no harm: mental, physical or financial harms
Major Sources of Crime Information
• Uniform Crime Report (UCR) - Part I and Part II offenses
• Published by the Federal Bureau of Investigation
• J. Edgar Hoover given permission in 1930 (FBI)
• Part II offenses
• 21 crimes (all non part I except traffic violations)
• Ex: fraud, embezzlement, weapons, vandalism, simple
assaults, sex crimes, drugs,
gambling, disorderly conduct and vagrancy.
• National Crime Victimization Survey
• Self-Report Studies
12/28/2021
8
FBI Part I Index Offenses
• Strengths
• Most consistent source of homicides and arrests
• Weakness
• Many crimes not reported, there are reporting errors, most
drug crimes omitted, white collar crimes omitted.
• Does not differentiate between attempted and completed.
• Cleared only means an arrest was made.
Crimes against the person
-Murder
-Rape
-Assault
-Robbery
Crimes against property
-Burglary
-Larceny
-Motor Vehicle Theft
-Arson
Victimization Surveys
• National Crime Victimization Survey (NCVS)
• Measure the extent of crime by interviewing individuals about
their
experiences as victims.
• Published by the Bureau of Justice Statistics
• 90,000 households, 160,000 people
• Cycle reports every three years.
• Covers time, place, offenders, weapons etc.
• Strengths:
• includes crimes not reported, careful sampling of gen. pop.
• Weakness: relies on victims memory and honesty
(telescoping).
• One index crime not included- which one?
12/28/2021
9
Self-Report Surveys
• A self-report study ask people to report their own criminal
acts in a
confidential interview or, more commonly, on an anonymous
questionnaire.
• These reports have demonstrated very high rates of l aw-
violating behavior
by seemingly law-abiding people.
• Most violate some laws.
• Strengths:
• includes non reported crimes, substance abuse and personal
information.
• Weakness:
• focus on petty crimes
• Honesty of self-reporting participants.
Crime Trends
• Crimes rose slowly between 1930-60.
• Rose fast from 1960-1980 and then dropped till 1984.
• Peeked: rose until 1991.
• Crimes have been decreasing since 1991.
• Between 2014 and 2018 there was a 4.7% increase in violent
crimes with a 14.6%
decrease in property crimes (Adler, Mueller, & Laufer, 2022, p.
44).
• More crime happens in the Southern states.
• More crime in urban areas
• More victimization within five miles of home and in your own
home
• 50% violent crimes happen between 6 a.m. – 6 p.m.
• 67% of sexual assaults, household larcenies, and 75% of motor
vehicle theft happens
at night.
• While most juvenile crimes occur after school 3 p.m. – 7 p.m.
12/28/2021
10
Age and Crime
• Peek Crimes years 16-24
• Siegel (2015) says 16 for property crime and
• 18 for violent crime
• Half of all arrest are of individual under age 25
• Juveniles account for 15% of all index crimes in 2006 at 8% of
pop.
• 25% of larceny theft and 50% of all arson arrests.
• Arrest rates decline after age 30
Aging Out Vs. Life Course Perspectives
• Aging out phenomenon
• Too old for crime – employment and relationships.
• Life Course: environmental factors
• Class, poverty, unemployment, peers and opportunity
• Chronic Offenders – a study of Philadelphia youth born in
1945
• 1972 publication on the males (9,945)
• 35% contact with police by age 18, 46% of the offenders were
one time offenders, 18% five or
more which was 6% of the total group studied know as the
Chronic 6%.
• The females (14,000
• 14% police contact by age 18, of those 60% one time
offenders, 33% repeat and 7% of total
group were chronic offenders
• Less violent crimes.
12/28/2021
11
Sex and Crime
• Males commit more crimes than females at all ages
• Arrest ratio: 3:1 however, the gap is closing
• 1960s females accounted for only 11% of total arrests.
• 2013 textbook stated 23% and now its 35% (Adler, Mueller &
Laufer, 2022).
• Female crimes are rising faster then the rate of boys.
• What Three offences do women commit more than men?
• Prostitution, shoplifting, and welfare fraud.
• Explanation: as women's social, economic and political power
increases so
has their criminal activity (movies: wonder women and star war
Jedi).
• While more poor and more patriarchal families tend to restrict
girls roles.
Race and Crime
• Blacks constitute 12.1% of USA pop. Yet 27% of all arrest for
index
crimes (Adler, Mueller, & Laufer, 2022).
• 50% of black urban males are arrested for an index crime once
in their
lifetime compared to 14% of white males.
• 18% of blacks serve some time in prison but only 3% of white
males.
• Blacks have a higher risk of death do to violence.
• Debating the explanations:
• Does it represent a bias CJ system? Or do Blacks commit
more crimes?
• While debates over class and crime remains controversial
there is no debate
over the class of those in prison? Most made less then $5,600
before prison.
• Lower class commit more serious crimes (burglary, robbery,
assaults and
sexual assaults).
Disruptive Innovation . . . in Reverse:
Adding a Geographical Dimension to
Disruptive Innovation Theory
Simone Corsi and Alberto Di Minin
Based on a literature review on disruptive innovation and
innovation from emerging econo-
mies, we offer an interpretation of a subset of reverse
innovation within the disruptive
innovation theory. We argue that the combination of these two
theories provides a useful
framework to look at emerging economies as sources of new
products and technological
solutions. Finally, we provide a new categorization of
disruptive innovation considering a
geographical dimension and future research directions.
Introduction
In a fast-changing world, where emergingeconomies are
constantly increasing their
importance in the global economy and where
innovation assumes an international dimen-
sion, an increasing number of scholars have
looked at the phenomenon of innovation in
emerging economies. Several authors are
investigating in what way these countries are
not only recipients (Vernon, 1966) but also
sources of innovation (Hart & Christensen,
2002; Immelt, Govindarajan & Trimble,
2009; Kenney, Massini & Murtha, 2009;
Govindarajan & Trimble, 2012).
Scholars refer to this trend in different ways,
depending on the aspect they focus on, such as
‘disruptive innovation from emerging econo-
mies’ (Hart & Christensen, 2002), ‘innovation
at the bottom of the pyramid’ (Prahalad, 2004),
‘cost-innovation’ (Zeng & Williamson, 2007) or
‘reverse innovation’ (Immelt, Govindarajan &
Trimble, 2009). However, the managerial lit-
erature is still lacking both a clear and solid
theoretical position and a strong theoretical
framework within which a new innovation
trend from emerging economies can be read
and interpreted (Govindarajan & Ramamurti,
2011). Hence, the aim of this paper is firstly to
critically review the literature concerning
innovation from emerging economies, and sec-
ondly to contribute a rationalization of the
related concepts, attempting a reinterpretation
of the concept of ‘reverse innovation’ (Immelt,
Govindarajan & Trimble, 2009; Govindarajan
& Trimble, 2012), defined as a type of ‘disrup-
tive innovation’ (Christensen, 1997).
Building on our review of the existing work
(see Appendix A and Table 1), we suggest that
the combination of these two frameworks pro-
vides a useful scheme to look at emerging
economies as sources of new products and
technological solutions.
In the last ten years, scholars have started to
look at companies that serve those markets in a
different way. Glocalization – adapting to
emerging markets products developed for
advanced ones – is in fact assumed to be par-
tially ‘blind’ or ineffective for the purpose of
serving emerging market needs, given its
ability to reach only the wealthier part of the
population. The new challenge of the twenty-
first century has been identified in the profit-
able development and sale of new products for
the mass markets of less affluent populations
of emerging economies that are currently not,
or only partially, served by multinational cor-
porations (MNCs). The innovation manage-
ment literature has produced a limited
number of studies (Hart & Christensen, 2002;
Prahalad, 2004; Immelt, Govindarajan &
Trimble, 2009; Hang, Chen & Subramanian,
2010; Govindarajan & Trimble, 2012), largely
based on anecdotal evidence, trying to identify
new ways of pursuing innovation in emerging
economies. Most of these studies build their
76 CREATIVITY AND INNOVATION MANAGEMENT
Volume 23 Number 1 2014
10.1111/caim.12043
© 2013 John Wiley & Sons Ltd
argument, more or less implicitly, on the well-
known ‘disruptive innovation’ paradigm as
defined by Christensen (1997) and Christensen
and Raynor (2003), further derived as disrup-
tive innovation in emerging economies in
Prahalad’s seminal work on innovation for the
‘bottom of the pyramid’ (BOP) (Prahalad,
2004).
Given the specificity of the context for and
in which these innovations need to be devel-
Table 1. Main Innovation Concepts Related to Emerging
Economies (Literature and Examples)
Concept Literature Examples
Disruptive
Innovation
Acee (2001); Anthony et al. (2006); Bower &
Christensen (1995); Cefis & Marsili (2006);
Charitou & Markides (2003); Christensen
(1997, 2006); Christensen & Overdorf
(2000); Christensen & Raynor (2003);
Christensen et al. (2000, 2006); Chesbrough
(2002); Corso & Pellegrini (2007); Danneels
(2004); Gilbert (2003); Gilbert & Bower
(2002); Glazer (2007); Govindarajan (2012);
Govindarajan & Kopalle (2006a, 2006b);
Govindarajan et al. (2011); Henderson
(2006); Johnson et al. (2008); Johnson
(2012); Kanter (2010); Kassicieh et al.
(2002); Mangelsdorf (2009); Markides
(2006); O’Reilly & Tushman (2004); Rafii &
Kampas (2002); Sandström, Magnusson &
Jörnmark (2009); Schmidt & Druehl (2008);
Simanis & Hart (2009); Suzuki & Kodama
(2004); Utterback & Acee (2005); Yu &
Hang (2010, 2011)
Hard disk drive; digital
photography; mobile
phone
Disruptive
Innovation
from Emerging
Economies
Hang et al. (2010); London & Hart (2004);
Markides (2012); Ray & Ray (2011); Schanz
et al. (2011)
Galanz’s microwave;
Suzlon’s windmills;
Haier’s washing
machine
Innovation for
the Bottom of
the Pyramid
Akula (2008); Anderson et al. (2010); Ansari
et al. (2012); Garrette & Karnani (2010);
Gino & Staats (2012); Hart & Christensen
(2002); Karamchandani et al. (2011);
Karnani (2007); Olsen & Boxembaum
(2009); Prahalad (2004, 2012); Prahalad &
Hammond (2002); Prahalad & Hart (2002);
Rangan et al. (2011); Simanis (2012); Wood
& Hamel (2002)
Aravind Eye Care’s
hospitals; ICICI Bank’s
microcredit; Casas
Bahia’s retailers
Cost Innovation Williamson (2010); Williamson & Zeng (2004,
2009); Zeng & Williamson (2007)
China International
Marine Containers
Group’s shipping
service; Dawning’s high
performance computers
Reverse
Innovation
Govindarajan and Trimble (2012); Immelt,
Govindarajan & Trimble (2009)
GE Healthcare’s ECG
machine; P&G’s
honey-based cold
remedy; P&G’s
feminine hygiene
product; Tata Nano
DISRUPTIVE INNOVATION . . . IN REVERSE 77
Volume 23 Number 1 2014
© 2013 John Wiley & Sons Ltd
oped, domestic companies seem to be best
placed to pursue them. By virtue of their
embeddedness, local market knowledge and
low cost approach, domestic companies
develop new product solutions for emerging
markets that challenge the activities of foreign
MNCs. This phenomenon has mostly been
referred to as ‘cost innovation’ (Zeng &
Williamson, 2007). Indeed, growing attention
has been paid to companies from emerging
economies and how in going global they
threaten western MNCs in the home markets
that they have dominated for decades.
Responding to this threat is a new challenge
for incumbent MNCs and, in our opinion, ‘dis-
ruptive innovation’ is a useful way to describe
the new trend that has recently been defined
as ‘reverse innovation’ (Immelt, Govindarajan
& Trimble, 2009). According to Immelt,
Govindarajan and Trimble (2009) and
Govindarajan and Trimble (2012), since most
current and future global economic growth is
likely to take place in emerging economies,
innovation specifically aimed at responding to
these markets is crucial. Indeed, new products
developed entirely in emerging markets for
emerging markets are likely to disrupt devel-
oped markets and open new business oppor-
tunities, as shown, for example, by Zeng and
Williamson (2007). This phenomenon thus
configures a process of innovation that no
longer sees developed economies as the locus
where new products are conceived, designed
and commercialized, but instead takes on the
role of the last recipient of innovations devel-
oped in and for emerging economies.
This paper builds on the disruptive innova-
tion literature and contrasts its analysis with
the concept of reverse innovation. We believe
we bring two theoretical contributions:
1. Adding a geographical dimension to disruptive
innovation. The original specification of
disruptive innovation is a theory that seeks
to explain dynamics within established
markets. However, a geographical dimen-
sion needs to be considered to make disrup-
tive innovation useful for interpreting
situations where the disruptors originate
from emerging markets.
2. A new look at disruptive and reverse innovation
side by side. Consistent with Govindarajan
and Trimble (2012), we emphasize that the
concepts of disruptive and reverse innova-
tion have an overlapping, though not a one-
to-one, relationship. By looking at these two
theories side by side, we are able to better
clarify similarities and differences. We dis-
tance ourselves from the claim that disrup-
tive innovation in reverse stems only from
an income gap. On the contrary, disruptive
in reverse rests not only on cost advantage
in the market segment but also on new
characteristics and features of the disrup-
tive product originated and tested in a
developing country and appreciated in
advanced countries.
This paper is organized as follows. In the
next section, we lay the foundations of our
analysis by reviewing disruptive innovation
theory. This will be used as our framework to
interpret the other sections that take into
account disruptive innovation as considered in
the different streams of literature related to
innovation in emerging economies. The third
section explores the dynamics of innovation at
the Bottom of the Pyramid (BOP), while the
fourth section investigates the conceptuali-
zation of disruptive innovation from emerging
economies. The concept of reverse innovation
is introduced in the fifth section and inter-
preted within the Disruptive Innovation
framework in the sixth section. The seventh
section provides a new categorization of Dis-
ruptive Innovation, considering a geographi-
cal dimension. Finally, conclusions and future
research directions are presented together
with selected research propositions.
Disruptive Innovation
Introduced in 1995 by Bower and Christensen,
the concept of disruptive innovation was
refined by Christensen in 1997 with his ‘Inn-
ovator’s Dilemma’, asking why great compa-
nies pursuing innovation in mainstream
markets suffer from market myopia and are
overtaken by entrant firms introducing prod-
ucts based on new, disruptive technologies.
To explain this phenomenon, Christensen
distinguishes between sustaining and disrup-
tive technologies. The former are technologies
that respond to an improvement, radical or
incremental, of ‘established products, along
the dimensions of performance that main-
stream customers in major markets have his-
torically valued’ (Christensen, 1997, p. xv).
Disruptive technologies, on the other hand,
are innovations for existing products but on
attributes that differ from those that are mainly
valued by mainstream customers. These inno-
vations, which initially underperform with
respect to the main attributes of sustaining
technologies, become disruptive when they
reach the same performance as the sustaining
innovations on the attributes valued by main-
stream customers. At this point, they displace
existing technologies and cause, in most cases,
the failure of incumbent firms. Christensen
describes as an example the evolution of the
78 CREATIVITY AND INNOVATION MANAGEMENT
Volume 23 Number 1 2014
© 2013 John Wiley & Sons Ltd
hard disk drive industry between 1976 and
1992. In this market, mainstream customers
constantly required improvements in two
attributes, total capacity and recording density.
The industry and incumbent firms were led by
this trend until an emerging segment asked for
improvements on different attributes, in par-
ticular, the size of drivers. At the beginning,
this segment remained marginal and was
mainly covered by small entrant firms that
could afford to do so by virtue of their rela-
tively limited cost structure, but while the
products offered gained improved perfor-
mance, including the mainstream segment
attributes, the market based on sustaining
technologies was progressively displaced,
causing the failure of incumbents.
In earlier works, Christensen (Bower &
Christensen, 1995; Christensen, 1997) refers to
disruptive technology only as an ‘innovation
that results in worse product performance in
mainstream markets’. It is also described as a
‘typically cheaper, simpler, smaller and fre-
quently more convenient to use’ version of an
existing product.
In an updated version of the concept,
Christensen and Raynor (2003) distinguish
between ‘low-end disruptions’ and ‘(new-
market) high-end disruptions’. The former are
those offering lower performance at a cheaper
price but no other performance improve-
ments, while the latter are described as prod-
ucts and services that offer better performance
on attributes that differ from those valued by
mainstream customers (e.g., the mobile phone,
initially low performing in reception, which
disrupted the market for home phones).
Christensen also asserts that disruptive
technologies should be framed as a marke-
ting, and not a technological, challenge
(Christensen, 2006; Glazer, 2007). Firms suc-
ceeding in disruptive innovations have a
strong attitude in interpreting and addressing
needs expressed by a market niche or a new
market segment. Thus, the challenge that
incumbent firms should overcome in develop-
ing and responding to disruptive innovatio ns
relates to the development of capabilities to
forecast market trends and attitudes as well as
‘riding’ new technological trajectories (Rafii &
Kampas, 2002; Charitou & Markides, 2003;
Suzuki & Kodama, 2004; Corso & Pellegrini,
2007).
Disruptive innovation has been used from
the very beginning to discuss innovation
dynamics taking place with the entry of new
companies in established and developed
markets (Chesbrough, 2002). One of the most
convincing responses provided by research-
ers, albeit widely discussed and doubted
(Danneels, 2004), is that these companies
should promote the creation of spin-off enter-
prises in order to better serve and interpret
emerging markets (O’Reilly & Tushman, 2004;
Kanter, 2010; Johnson, 2012). The creation of a
separate organization of a smaller dimension
with large autonomy allows the problem of
resource allocation that is too mainstream cus-
tomer oriented to be overcome. Matching the
initially small market size to the size of
the investment potentially enables the new
company to be profitable (Kassicieh et al.,
2002; Anthony, Eyring & Gibson, 2006; Cefis &
Marsili, 2006; Sandström, Magnusson &
Jörnmark, 2009).
Since its coinage, the concept of disruptive
innovation has been widely discussed from
different perspectives (Christensen, Bohmer &
Kenagy, 2000; Christensen, Johnson & Rigby,
2002; Gilbert & Bower, 2002; Gilbert, 2003;
Danneels, 2004; Christensen et al., 2006;
Henderson, 2006; Johnson, Christensen &
Kagermann, 2008; Schmidt & Druehl, 2008;
Yu & Hang, 2010, 2011). In particular,
Govindarajan and Kopalle (2006a, 2006b)
make a clear distinction between low-end and
high-end disruptions based on the level of
radicalness of disruptive innovations (techno-
logically more radical in high-end disruptions,
technologically less radical in low-end disrup-
tions). The authors also make a clear distinc-
tion between innovations that are radical and
disruptive and merely radical, stating that
radicalness is a technology-based concept
while disruptiveness is a market-based
concept. Analogously, Markides (2006) draws a
clear distinction between different kinds of
disruptive innovations: technological, business
model and new-to-the-world product innova-
tions. From this distinction and from the work
of Utterback (2004), Acee (2001) and Utterback
and Acee (2005), who recognized the impor-
tance of disruptive technologies not in the fact
that they displace existing products but in
their ability to enlarge existing markets and
provide new functionalities, Govindarajan and
Kopalle add rigour to an expanded view of
disruptive innovation, including both high-
end and low-end disruptions and define the
concept as follow (2006a, p. 190):
A disruptive innovation introduces a differ-
ent set of features, performance and price
attributes relative to the existing product, an
unattractive combination for mainstream
customers at the time of product introduc-
tion because of inferior performance on the
attributes these customers value and/or a
high price – although a different customer
segment may value the new attributes. Sub-
sequent developments over time, however,
raise the new product’s attributes to a level
DISRUPTIVE INNOVATION . . . IN REVERSE 79
Volume 23 Number 1 2014
© 2013 John Wiley & Sons Ltd
sufficient to satisfy mainstream customers,
thus attracting more of the mainstream
market.
In the examples of disruptive technologies
provided by Christensen (1997) and
Christensen and Raynor (2003), the new
market segment that adopts the disruptive
solution belongs to the same market where
incumbent companies operate. The emergence
of new technologies triggers interest within
the mainstream segment where these incum-
bents operate, hence rendering access to the
disruptive offering (initially not desired)
also possible to mainstream customers
(Govindarajan, Kopalle & Danneels, 2011).
In conclusion, we can argue that disruptive
innovation is a theory that seeks to explain
changes and new entries into established
markets. The result of disruptive innovation is
visible when mainstream customers switch to
the new disruptive product that is gaining
market share on established markets.
What if the new disruptive solution has
been brought to maturity and has triggered
interest in markets that are geographically
distant and disconnected from established
markets? Disruptive innovation theory was
not developed, and is as yet too unrefined, to
explain this phenomenon.
Innovation at the Bottom of the
Pyramid (BOP)
While the disruptive innovation paradigm
explores the dynamics originating within the
hub of an industry, a new approach was devel-
oped to understand what was taking place in
emerging economies and their markets
(Karnani, 2007; Akula, 2008; Gino & Staats,
2012). This orientation brought scholars to
thinking of emerging economies as focal
markets to which companies should pay
increasing attention and develop a new R&D
orientation (Prahalad & Hart, 2002).
Traditionally, MNCs delocalized their R&D-
oriented foreign direct investment (FDI) in
emerging economies for two main reasons
(Gassmann & Han, 2004; Von Zedtwitz, 2004):
• access to local markets,
• access to high-skilled research personnel at
a lower cost.
Following these two drivers, most R&D
carried out by foreign MNCs in emerging
countries consisted in the adaptation of global
products to the specific needs of the local
market. R&D, crucial for the development of
new products, has traditionally been undis-
closed by headquarters (Patel & Pavitt, 1991; Di
Minin & Bianchi, 2011), and this is particularly
true of R&D internationalization in emerging
economies.
The new perspective in the early 2000s was
that emerging market potential was not
exploited with the previous approach and that
a new type of innovation management had to
be developed. Companies noted that respond-
ing to local market needs with a simple local
adaptation of global products developed in
their (mainly) western headquarters (glocali-
zation) was ineffective in exploiting the entire
potential of these growing markets (London &
Hart, 2004; Rangan, Chu & Petkoski, 2011).
Prahalad and Hart (2002), and later on
Prahalad (2004), introduced the new approach
to emerging economies as a source of signifi-
cant profit generation through the develop-
ment and commercialization of ad hoc products
and services for the markets of the poor
(Garrette & Karnani, 2010; Simanis, 2012).
Prahalad’s approach is expressed in the title of
his 2004 book The Fortune at the Bottom of the
Pyramid: Eradicating Poverty through Profits. The
author identifies a large opportunity both for
local and MNCs operating in emerging econo-
mies and provides examples such as ICICI
Bank, which provides Indian rural populations
with bank credit for small projects (which in
turn become profitable and make them able to
return the loan with low interest), or Voxiva,
which developed a text message-based plat-
form for favouring communication between
urban and health centres in Peru. Both projects,
based on low cost and pricing strategies, faced
an experimental stage for the purpose of vali-
dating their economic feasibility and soon
moved forward, replicating their model in
other emerging countries and contexts.
According to Prahalad’s perspective, MNCs
serving only the top of the pyramid (the
wealthier part of the population) in emerging
economies suffer from business myopia in a
way that closely recalls the marketing chal-
lenge that Christensen’s incumbent firms
faced in developing disruptive innovation for
new or emerging market niches.
What is of great interest to us is that,
although there is no direct and explicit link
between these theories, the BOP concept
shares some similarities with the disruptive
innovation theory (Hart & Christensen, 2002;
Prahalad & Hammond, 2002; Prahalad, 2012).
It suggests developing products and services
for a market segment requesting different
attributes than those of mainstream customers
(Wood & Hamel 2002; Seelos & Mair, 2007;
Anderson, Markides & Kupp, 2010) and, in
particular, access to the same technology at a
much lower price. In reality, it addresses a
80 CREATIVITY AND INNOVATION MANAGEMENT
Volume 23 Number 1 2014
© 2013 John Wiley & Sons Ltd
market that does not yet exist, seemingly con-
figuring what Govindarajan and Kopalle
(2006a, 2006b) identify as disruptive innova-
tion that creates a new market. In our opinion,
innovation at the BOP cannot be easily, or
entirely, assimilated with disruptive innova-
tion theory. We will explain why in the next
section, explicitly linking the BOP to the dis-
ruptive innovation paradigm.
Disruptive Innovations from
Emerging Economies
Parallel to the work on ‘Serving the Bottom of
the Pyramid’, a further wave of exploration
was initiated by scholars linking the disruptive
innovation theory and Prahalad’s non-served
markets of the poorest in emerging economies
(Hart & Christensen, 2002; London & Hart,
2004).
The argument of scholars applying disrup-
tive innovation to explain the success of new
products originating from emerging econo-
mies is as follows: foreign MNCs develop
products for emerging markets and later use
them to penetrate the low-end segment of
developed markets in the US and Europe, and
domestic firms leverage on their cost structure
and knowledge of the domestic context to
serve local, and later developed, markets (Ray
& Ray, 2011; Schanz et al., 2011; Markides,
2012).
To the best of our knowledge, Hart and
Christensen (2002) for the first time introduced
the link between disruptive innovation theory
and emerging economies. Their argument is
clearly in line with Prahalad’s work referring
to ‘innovation from the base of the pyramid’.
The authors propose examples of Asian com-
panies that succeeded in introducing disrup-
tive innovations in low-income countries,
enabling poor people to afford certain types of
technological products and generating profits
for themselves.
Recently, Hang, Chen and Subramanian
(2010) demonstrated four cases of Asian com-
panies that, starting from their low-income
markets (China and India), developed disrup-
tive products. Galanz and Haier, for example,
developed ad hoc products for penetrating the
Chinese domestic market and responding to
specific local needs (a microwave for Galanz
and a washing machine for Haier). Once they
succeeded in China, they were able to export
their product to developed countries serving a
market segment that was ignored by incum-
bents due to its size, a market segment that
was eager for low-cost products with strong
energy and room-saving attributes and that
did not care about traditional attributes for
those items such as capacity. After a few years
of internal and external R&D investment, both
companies were able to penetrate also the
high-end of advanced economies’ markets,
disrupting local incumbents. The success
pursued in these markets brought them per-
formance improvements on attributes that had
at first been neglected and valued by main-
stream customers in developed economies.
This pushed them to invest globally and to
steadily grow in developed economies.
We believe that in both works cited above,
the disruptive innovation concept is used in a
way that differs from the traditional applica-
tion of the concept within established markets
in developed economies. The traditionally
defined disruptive innovation paradigm
(Bower & Christensen, 1995; Christensen,
1997) claims that new products (or services)
are considered disruptive when they respond
to an ignored and new market segment that is
usually small, unprofitable for incumbents and
has differentiated needs in terms of product
attributes. Could we say that the idea of inno-
vation originating in emerging markets pre-
sented by Hart and Christensen (2002) is
indeed a disruptive innovation? We think this
is true only in part, and that three limitations
need to be considered in relation to the char-
acteristics of disruptiveness mentioned above.
In particular, we need to consider (1) the
categorization of mainstream and non-
mainstream customers, (2) market size, and (3)
disruptive innovators (see Table 2):
1. Companies operating in emerging econo-
mies have traditionally served those
markets adopting a glocalization approach
to market segmentation, thus serving cus-
tomers that correspond and share similar
characteristics to those segments served
back in their country of origin or in devel-
oped markets. These are their mainstream
customers, who might represent the great
majority at home but in emerging econo-
mies represent only the top of the pyramid.
Adopting a marketing perspective instead,
as the disruptive challenge requires us to
(Christensen, 1997; Danneels, 2004), main-
stream customers in emerging markets
should be defined as the large part of the
population (be it individuals or companies)
that cannot afford expensive state-of-the-art
technology and that are partly served by
local companies that can interpret their
needs and respond to them thanks to their
cost structure.
2. One of the main challenges that incumbent
firms face when developing or responding
to disruptive innovations in their markets is
that the size of the emerging market with
DISRUPTIVE INNOVATION . . . IN REVERSE 81
Volume 23 Number 1 2014
© 2013 John Wiley & Sons Ltd
different requirements is too small to cover
the development costs of new products
(Christensen, 1997; Christensen & Raynor,
2003). Indeed, the size of the market does
not match the size of the company and its
related cost structure as it does in the case
of small entrants or spin-off companies.
This is not true in emerging economies,
where the market served by innovations, as
in the cases presented in Hart and
Christensen (2002) and Hang, Chen and
Subramanian (2010), is much bigger than
that served by glocal products, so that the
market size is potentially huge, assuming
that access to these market segments is
feasible.
3. Disruptive innovations in developed econo-
mies generally come from a small entrant
firm (e.g., a start-up company) that is gen-
erated by either a new entrepreneurial
activity or a spin-off company from an
incumbent firm (Bower & Christensen,
1995; Christensen, 1997; Walsh, Kirchhoff &
Newbert, 2002; Christensen & Raynor,
2003). The generation of disruptive innova-
tions in emerging economies could be
developed by domestic companies that
naturally have a cost structure and a market
orientation that fits the local environment
and by subsidiaries of MNCs that have
evolved and gained enough autonomy to
develop new products. The case of compa-
nies from emerging markets is well
described by Zeng and Williamson (2007)
who report on how innovations developed
by Chinese companies are disrupting global
markets by primarily leveraging on new,
low cost based, business models. The inno-
vative approach of these companies is
defined by the authors as ‘cost innovation’.
Reverse Innovation
In the previous sections, we showed how dis-
ruptive innovation theory does not adequately
fit the description of innovations developed
for emerging economies and afterwards
‘exported’ back to developed economies.
‘Reverse innovation’ (Govindarajan, 2009;
Immelt, Govindarajan & Trimble, 2009;
Govindarajan & Trimble, 2012) is a more suit-
able framework that helps us understand this
trend. This new line of research emphasizes
the role of emerging economies as the new
laboratory in the global economy and argues
that innovation is less likely to come from, and
is adopted in, developed countries first, but is
conceived and adopted in emerging econo-
mies first to then be introduced to developed
markets. It is then ‘exported’ to the developed
economies. These dynamics reverse the inno-
vation process as intended in the prior litera-
ture and managerial practice. The reasons that
support such an inverted process lie in the
market growth of the developing countries
that are supporting and leading the global
economy.
In their 2009 article ‘How GE is Disrupting
Itself’, Immelt, Govindarajan and Trimble
show how GE is benefiting from its presence
in the markets of emerging economies, specifi-
cally China and India, to develop break-
through innovations that are introduced and
successfully commercialized first in develop-
ing countries and later, when performance
improvements are acceptable, in developed
countries. They provide clear examples for GE
Healthcare developing and perfecting prod-
ucts in both China (Immelt, Govindarajan &
Trimble, 2009) and India (Govindarajan &
Trimble, 2012) before selling them in those
markets first and in advanced ones later on,
disrupting existing products in some markets
as a result of performance improvements
on the attributes most valued by mainstream
customers.
The authors stress the importance of local
growth teams (LGTs) as new units, independ-
ent from their MNC headquarters (HQ), built
from scratch in emerging economies. They are
responsible for the complete development and
commercialization of products leveraging HQ
technology but developing completely new
offerings that match the market they operate
in. While GE Healthcare is a well-known
example, there are other cases that present
similar innovation paths. Esaote, an Italian
medium-sized company that designs and
manufactures medical diagnostic systems, is
currently sourcing product ideas for the global
market from its R&D laboratory located in
Shenzhen (Corsi & Di Minin, 2012).
These cases explain how in order to
compete in emerging economies, foreign
MNCs have to rely on LGTs in order to
develop innovations that fit local needs and
overcome local constraints. At the same time,
they do not neglect the glocalization paradigm
in line with which MNCs have to continue to
operate to serve high-end markets and build
part of the technological knowledge that is
essential for the activities of LGTs in emerging
economies.
Overlapping Areas between
Disruptive and Reverse Innovation
Given the above considerations, the disruptive
innovation theory can provide a useful tool for
interpreting the phenomenon of innovation
82 CREATIVITY AND INNOVATION MANAGEMENT
Volume 23 Number 1 2014
© 2013 John Wiley & Sons Ltd
from emerging economies. As we showed in
the above sections, scholars have already iden-
tified this opportunity, but we think it needs to
be refined and integrated with reverse innova-
tion to effectively frame a reversed cycle of
innovation. The characteristics that Immelt,
Govindarajan and Trimble (2009) and
Govindarajan and Trimble (2012) list and illus-
trate to describe reverse innovation partly
match those described in the previous sections
of this paper recalling disruptive innova-
tion theory as illustrated by Bower and
Christensen (1995), Christensen (1997), Acee
(2001), Christensen and Raynor (2003),
Utterback and Acee (2005) and Govindarajan
and Kopalle (2006a, 2006b). In particular,
under specific circumstances reverse innova-
tion shares great similarities with the idea of
disruptive innovation from emerging econo-
mies as illustrated by Hart and Christensen
(2002), Zeng and Williamson (2007) and Hang,
Chen and Subramanian (2010).
Govindarajan and Trimble (2009) responded
to this parallelism themselves following the
requests of some readers of their paper who
asked for clarification between disruptive
innovation and reverse innovation. In one of
Govindarajan’s blog posts (30 September
20091), they list a set of conditions that reverse
innovation can originate from, stating that the
one concerning a lower price offer is the only
one configuring it also as a disruptive innova-
tion. The same issue is addressed by
Govindarajan and Trimble (2012). They thus
consider disruptive innovation only from a
price/performance point of view, and not as a
market widener or as a provider of new
functionalities, implicitly stating that disrup-
tive innovation can only have a lower price.
We do not believe this is completely true.
Referring back to Govindarajan’s works
on disruptive innovation, we note that
Govindarajan and Kopalle (2006b) define dis-
ruptive innovation as ‘a powerful means for
broadening and developing new markets and
providing new functionality, which, in turn,
disrupt existing market linkages’.
Therefore, the focus now lies in the alterna-
tive attributes that are offered by the innova-
tion in relation to an existing product. These
new products are able to penetrate the market
starting from early adopters and improve per-
formance in the ‘mainstream’ thanks to the
experience accumulated in serving the new
segment. In line with Christensen and Raynor
(2003) and Utterback and Acee (2005),
Govindarajan and Kopalle (2006a) define dis-
ruptive innovation in the way presented in the
second section of this paper and include both
new, low-end and high-end attributes to exist-
ing products that initially are tempting only to
new customers (thus not necessarily price-
focused) or the most price-sensitive main-
stream customers, but in developing over time
they also gain the attention of mainstream cus-
tomers and the market.
In summary, Govindarajan and Trimble
(2012) state that reverse innovation has five
drivers, named ‘gaps’ (performance, infra-
structure, sustainability, regulatory, prefer-
ences), but the examples they provide in
their work (Immelt, Govindarajan & Trimble,
2009; Govindarajan & Ramamurti, 2011;
Govindarajan & Trimble, 2012) stress funda-
mentally the income (or performance) gap
(Logitech Mouse in China, P&G feminine
hygiene product in Mexico, Deere Tractor in
India, Harman infotainment system in India
and China), and indirectly lead us to under-
stand that reverse innovation takes the direc-
tion of a potential disruptive effect only when
an equivalent income gap can be found isolat-
ing a segment of the market in an advanced
economy. While we acknowledge that indeed
the income gap is a key driver, the emphasis of
Christensen’s low-end disruptive innovation is
on new markets being created, and new value
networks displacing the old ones. Such dyna-
mics in reverse-disruptive innovation happen
not only when a company from emerging coun-
tries enters advanced ones to serve the needs of
a less affluent market segment, but indeed dis-
ruption occurs when the technological evolu-
tion and market experience lead this offering to
go from the niche to the main market. In these
situations of reverse-disruptive innovations,
we indeed identify the following common
elements between reverse innovation and dis-
ruptive innovation: the same risks of
cannibalizations for companies that have previ-
ously invested in the same industries for main-
stream customers (Govindarajan & Kopalle,
2006a, 2006b; Immelt, Govindarajan & Trimble,
2009), which is also a tool for measuring the
potentiality of firms to develop disruptive
innovations (Govindarajan & Kopalle, 2006b).
As anticipated by Williamson and Zeng
(2004, 2009), Seely Brown and Hagel (2005),
Williamson (2010) and Zeng and Williamson
(2007) with reference to business models, dis-
ruptive innovations are a tool to pre-empt
giants from emerging economies that are
going global with a new price-performance
offering, which is exactly the same purpose of
reverse innovation (Immelt, Govindarajan &
Trimble, 2009).
LGTs that Immelt, Govindarajan and
Trimble (2009) and Govindarajan and Trimble
(2012) explain as crucial for the development of
innovations for emerging economies mirror the
spin-off companies described by Christensen
and Overdorf (2000), Christensen, Bohmer and
DISRUPTIVE INNOVATION . . . IN REVERSE 83
Volume 23 Number 1 2014
© 2013 John Wiley & Sons Ltd
Kenagy (2000), Christensen and Raynor (2003)
and Danneels (2004, 2006), as the best solution
for incumbents that want to compete with or
develop disruptive innovations.
We therefore believe that disruptive innova-
tion theory can be a rich tool for interpreting a
subset of reverse innovation as defined by
Immelt, Govindarajan and Trimble (2009) and
Govindarajan and Trimble (2012). Adopting
this perspective, we believe we can enrich the
disruptive innovation theory from an emerg-
ing country perspective.
Geographic Dimension of
Disruptive Innovation
As discussed in the previous section, it is pos-
sible to interpret a subset of reverse innova-
tion, and the considerations that follow are
limited to this subset, as a particular manifes-
tation of disruptive innovation. In fact,
Govindarajan and Trimble seem to suggest the
same by proposing an uphill flow of reverse
innovation to marginalized first and, often,
mainstream markets in advanced economies
(2012: 22). Can we thus simply generalize the
findings and implications of disruptive inno-
vation originating from developed countries to
situations of reverse innovation?
The answer is no. Such a generalization does
not work, since success stories of disruptive
innovation originating from developed
markets differ substantially from success
stories that export successful products back to
developed markets that were first introduced
in emerging economies. Table 2 summarizes
the main differences discussed below:
• Early market: in disruptive innovation
theory, the market segment served by the
new technology is characterized by early
adopters. In reverse innovation, the early
market is instead represented by the large
part of the population, or BOP, that has no
access to the established technology because
it is either too expensive or too complex.
This is hardly the case with early adopters
and developed markets. These differences
should lead to completely different market-
ing strategies.
• Actors: the small size of the early market in
disruptive innovation theory makes spin-off
companies or small new entrants the only
actors able to serve this market profitably.
On the other hand, the vast size of the new
market segment to be served in emerging
economies allows both local start-ups,
foreign MNC subsidiaries and large local
companies to make profit from it by exploit-
ing economies of scale. The key question is
whether local start-ups will find the com-
plementary assets to reach international
markets. Conversely, there are examples
(see the case of Aravind Eye Care in
Prahalad, 2004) of successful disruptors in
emerging economies which were not able to
expand internationally.
• Expansion: the evolution of disruptive prod-
ucts conceived in and for developed
markets brings innovative technologies to
commercialization in the same markets as
the established ones, while disruptive prod-
ucts introduced in and for developing
economies allow foreign MNCs and domes-
tic companies to export their evolved
disruptions to mainstream markets in
developed countries, configuring a process
of reverse innovation.
• Maturation of technology: the technological
evolution of disruptive innovations is the
same in both cases, but while in disruptive
innovation theory this occurs in the same
country market, in reverse innovation we
see it happening in developing economies
and brought to developed economies once
the technology has evolved.
• Challenges: the development of a technology
on a new trajectory puts new entrants in
established markets in competition to reach
new technological standards. In emerging
economies, the main challenge is the diffi-
culty of reaching a vast market that often
lacks adequate complementary assets (such
as distribution and logistics infrastruc-
tures). Furthermore, cultural and institu-
tional differences make it difficult for
foreign firms to understand and properly
respond to market needs.
• Basis of competition/success: in traditional dis-
ruptive innovation theory, the ‘battle’ is won
by the company that develops the new tech-
nology better and faster, satisfying at first
the request for new attributes and, along
within technological evolution, catching up
on the mainstream attributes. In reverse
innovation, competition is instead based on
the ability to develop a new business model
that allows companies to serve a large
portion of the market in order to achieve
large sales volumes and economies of scale.
Research Propositions and a
Research Agenda
In light of the discussion presented in this
paper, we can conclude that reverse innovation
has the potential to take the form of disruptive
innovation that originates not from the same
geographical market that incumbent compa-
nies dominate, but rather from the markets of
84 CREATIVITY AND INNOVATION MANAGEMENT
Volume 23 Number 1 2014
© 2013 John Wiley & Sons Ltd
T
ab
le
2.
D
if
fe
re
n
ce
s
be
tw
ee
n
D
is
ru
pt
iv
e
In
n
ov
at
io
n
in
E
m
er
gi
n
g
an
d
D
ev
el
op
ed
E
co
n
om
ie
s
C
h
ar
ac
te
ri
st
ic
s/
L
o
ca
ti
o
n
E
ar
ly
M
ar
k
et
A
ct
o
rs
E
xp
an
si
o
n
M
at
u
ra
ti
o
n
o
f
T
ec
h
n
o
lo
g
y
C
h
al
le
n
g
es
C
o
m
p
et
e/
S
u
cc
ee
d
b
as
ed
o
n
D
is
ru
pt
iv
e
In
n
ov
at
io
n
in
D
ev
el
op
ed
C
ou
n
tr
ie
s
•
A
d
va
n
ce
d
/
In
n
ov
at
iv
e
ea
rl
y
ad
o
p
te
rs
se
ek
in
g
to
b
e
“e
d
u
ca
te
d
”
an
d
to
tr
y
th
e
n
ew
te
ch
n
o
lo
g
y.
•
Ty
p
ic
al
ly
sm
al
l,
ad
va
n
ce
d
n
ic
h
e
Sp
in
o
ff
s
o
r
n
ew
en
tr
an
ts
ab
le
to
b
e
fl
ex
ib
le
en
o
u
g
h
to
se
rv
e
th
e
n
ic
h
e
In
to
m
ai
n
st
re
am
m
ar
k
et
o
f
th
e
sa
m
e
co
u
n
tr
y
th
ro
u
g
h
a
p
ro
ce
ss
o
f
u
p
g
ra
d
in
g
“m
ai
n
st
re
am
te
ch
n
o
lo
g
ic
al
at
tr
ib
u
te
s”
P
ro
fi
ts
fr
o
m
ea
rl
y
m
ar
k
et
s
ar
e
in
v
es
te
d
(d
ri
v
en
b
y
ea
rl
y
m
ar
k
et
re
q
u
es
ts
)
in
to
th
e
d
ev
el
o
p
m
en
t
o
f
te
ch
n
o
lo
g
y
th
at
is
im
p
ro
v
ed
w
it
h
re
sp
ec
t
to
th
at
fr
o
m
in
cu
m
b
en
ts
th
ro
u
g
h
p
at
h
d
ep
en
d
en
ce
St
an
d
ar
d
b
at
tl
e
am
o
n
g
st
st
ar
t-
u
p
s
•
Sp
ee
d
o
f
d
ev
el
o
p
m
en
t
•
H
ig
h
m
ar
g
in
s
o
n
ce
th
e
in
cu
m
b
en
ts
h
av
e
b
ee
n
d
is
ru
p
te
d
D
is
ru
pt
iv
e
In
n
ov
at
io
n
in
an
d
fr
om
E
m
er
gi
n
g
E
co
n
om
ie
s
•
L
ar
g
e
m
aj
o
ri
ty
o
f
p
o
p
u
la
ti
o
n
w
it
h
n
o
m
ea
n
s
to
g
et
to
es
ta
b
li
sh
ed
te
ch
n
o
lo
g
ie
s
•
Ty
p
ic
al
ly
la
rg
e
B
O
P
Su
b
si
d
ia
ri
es
o
f
M
N
C
s
an
d
la
rg
e
lo
ca
l
co
m
p
an
ie
s
th
at
ar
e
ab
le
to
ex
p
lo
it
ec
o
n
o
m
ie
s
o
f
sc
al
e
In
to
m
ai
n
st
re
am
m
ar
k
et
o
f
em
er
g
ed
co
u
n
tr
ie
s
th
ro
u
g
h
a
p
ro
ce
ss
o
f
re
v
er
se
in
n
ov
at
io
n
Sa
m
e
p
ro
ce
ss
o
f
m
at
u
ra
ti
o
n
•
D
is
tr
ib
u
ti
o
n
in
va
st
m
ar
k
et
s
•
R
eq
u
ir
em
en
t
to
ac
ce
ss
m
ar
k
et
n
ee
d
s
•
R
eq
u
ir
em
en
t
to
u
n
d
er
st
an
d
an
d
re
sp
o
n
d
to
m
ar
k
et
n
ee
d
s
•
V
o
lu
m
e
•
C
o
st
s
an
d
re
o
rg
an
iz
at
io
n
o
f
p
ro
d
u
ct
s/
se
rv
ic
es
DISRUPTIVE INNOVATION . . . IN REVERSE 85
Volume 23 Number 1 2014
© 2013 John Wiley & Sons Ltd
emerging economies, where a technology/
product has been commercialized to fit the
characteristics of those markets, particularly
serving the vast bottom of the pyramid.
The disruptive innovation framework pro-
vides us with the dynamics to look at innova-
tion that originates for emerging economies.
However, the challenges, evolution and
factors leading to success or failure of reverse
innovation are different from those that are
relevant when disruptive innovation originates
from a developed market. We therefore argue
that instead of simply generalizing the find-
ings of disruptive innovation to emerging
economies, future studies should take into
consideration innovations that originate for
those markets. We have thus added a geo-
graphical dimension to the disruptive innova-
tion paradigm, explaining the variables that
should be taken into account when consider-
ing such an innovation emerging in develop-
ing economies.
Given the above considerations we develop
four research propositions that we believe may
be of inspiration for innovation management
scholars and thus fuel future research.
Christensen and Raynor (2003) have illus-
trated the importance of spin-out companies as
a way to overcome the innovator’s dilemma.
Incumbents are often disrupted by new
entrants because they are not able to see
emerging technologies entering the market
and to address new needs while improving
also on attributes of the technologies adopted
by the mainstream market. The establishment
of a new autonomous company that rises from
an incumbent firm has the potential to
respond to the marketing challenge posed by
disruptive technologies and to address a new
emerging market. Market myopia can also be
found in the case of advanced MNCs that
operate in emerging markets, often trying
to commercialize only small adaptations of
their products previously developed for the
advanced markets. Hence, the ordination of a
subsidiary operating in emerging markets
with autonomy regarding product develop-
ment can be an important source of reverse
innovation with disruptive potential also in
advanced markets.
RP1: Subsidiaries of ‘advanced’ MNCs in
emerging economies can act as the spin-off com-
panies theorized by Christensen as a way to
overcome the innovator’s dilemma.
Scholars should thus focus on organiza-
tional and host country factors that may affect
subsidiary autonomy as well as its ability to
trigger processes of reverse knowledge trans-
fer (Ambos, Ambos & Schlegelmilch, 2006). Of
particular importance is the role of people
appointed to manage the subsidiary. These
managers are in fact vectors of innovation
stimuli coming from emerging markets. They
thus need to know well both the company
culture and its technological endowment in
order to optimally interpret the best means for
product development. At the same time, they
need to have enough authority with their
headquarters for the ideas they propose that
may diverge from the traditional technological
path their company follows to be taken into
appropriate consideration.
In order for companies to be able to trigger
reverse innovation processes, two essential
conditions need to be present: a strong knowl-
edge of emerging market needs and business
environment and a good technological base.
This is not always the case for a single
company. Very often an ‘advanced’ MNC has a
strong technological base (given by its experi-
ence and the quality of its R&D engineers), but
lacks a deep knowledge of emerging markets.
On the other hand, ‘emerging’ companies
know very well their home market but often
lack an appropriate technological base given
their relatively short history.
RP2: Despite a liberalization trend of emerging
economies which allows foreign companies to
operate more freely, we will see a new
technology-focused generation of joint ventures
between ‘advanced’ and ‘emerging’ MNCs.
As in the past, the creation of joint ventures
and other forms of interaction between foreign
and local firms seem to be relevant. But while
in the past foreign companies were legally
obligated by host country FDI policies to
engage in joint ventures in order to get access
to the emerging economies’ markets (see, for
example, the case of China described by Long,
2005), this need for cooperation may increas-
ingly emerge with the aim of merging comple-
mentary competences for developing products
that are globally marketable. This potential
trend suggests a focus on new drivers of
cooperation between foreign MNCs and local
firms in emerging economies, as they may
diverge from previous ones. In particular, we
believe it would be interesting to see how
R&D teams of such joint ventures are com-
posed and what the dynamics occurring
between foreign and local engineers are.
This intensification of interaction between
foreign and local firms in emerging economies
can be read and extended from an open inno-
vation perspective.
RP3: Open innovation dynamics will facilitate
the triggering of reverse innovation processes.
Future research should try to understand
whether and how open innovation dynamics
86 CREATIVITY AND INNOVATION MANAGEMENT
Volume 23 Number 1 2014
© 2013 John Wiley & Sons Ltd
are different in an emerging economy context.
Intuitively, ‘advanced’ MNCs operating in
emerging markets can benefit from outbound
open innovation performed by local compa-
nies that are willing to share or sell their
product ideas or nascent technologies for
developing and selling them worldwide. This
could lead to inbound open innovation per-
formed by foreign MNCs which source tech-
nologies from local firms or universities and
research institutions.
Strong intellectual property regimes are
required to implement an innovation strategy
that is based on an open model. This may be a
problem in developing countries since they
are shown to have weak intellectual property
regimes (IPR) (Zhao, 2006).
RP4: As emerging economies will strengthen
their intellectual property regimes, we will see
more reverse innovation processes.
Despite the fact that foreign MNCs are
worried about their IP protection in emerging
economies, recent contributions show how this
problem can be overcome in developing econo-
mies such as China (Keupp, Beckenbauer &
Gassmann, 2009; Quan & Chesbrough, 2010),
presenting successful cases of foreign compa-
nies that implement R&D activities in China,
providing useful tools for overcoming the risk
of IP violation. Future research has the oppor-
tunity to study how IP strategies of companies
operating in emerging markets will evolve
along with the evolution of these countries and
how these will probably change, passing from
having a local perspective to a more interna-
tional or global breadth. An evolved patent
system would help researchers to investigate
even further the reverse innovation processes
by using patents to identify innovations origi-
nating from emerging economies which are
potentially disruptive, as has already been
done for disruptive technologies (Pilkington,
Dyerson & Tissier, 2002).
In terms of managerial implications, this
paper provides companies with a set of basic
attributes of reverse innovation with disrup-
tive potential. Managers of ‘advanced’ MNCs
can thus use these insights to both trigger
innovation processes for their own companies,
leveraging on their technological basis, or
interpret actions underpinned by competitors
from emerging economies who are trying to
enter foreign advanced markets. Managers of
‘emerging’ MNCs can identify patterns of
technology and market development which
occurred from an emerging to an advanced
market.
As reverse innovation dynamics unfold, we
expect to see new business models evolve,
new forms of interaction between MNCs and
local partners, as well as new opportunities for
entrepreneurs trying to adapt technologies
across distant markets and to explore the role
of emerging markets as the new laboratory of
the global economy.
Note
1. We are aware that an author’s blog is not a strong
source but, given the novelty of the topic, the
explanation provided in this post is crucial for
understanding the concept.
References
Acee, H.J. (2001) Disruptive Technologies: an
Extended View. SM Thesis, Management
of Technology, Massachusetts Institute of
Technology.
Akula, V. (2008) Business Basics at the Base
of the Pyramid. Harvard Business Review, 86,
53–57.
Ambos, T.C., Ambos, B. and Schlegelmilch, B.B.
(2006) Learning from Foreign Subsidiaries: An
Empirical Investigation of Headquarters’ Benefits
from Reverse Knowledge Transfers. International
Business Review, 15, 294–312.
Anderson, J.L., Markides, C. and Kupp, M. (2010)
The Last Frontier: Market Creation in Conflict
Zones, Deep Rural Areas, and Urban Slums. Cali-
fornia Management Review, 52, 6–28.
Ansari, S., Munir, K. and Gregg, T. (2012) Impact at
the ‘Bottom of the Pyramid’: The Role of Social
Capital in Capability Development and Commu-
nity Empowerment. Journal of Management
Studies, 49, 813–42.
Anthony, S.D., Eyring, M. and Gibson, L. (2006)
Mapping your Innovation Strategy. Harvard Busi-
ness Review, 84, 104–13.
Bower, J.L. and Christensen, C.M. (1995) Disruptive
Technologies: Catching the Wave. Harvard Busi-
ness Review, 73, 43–53.
Cefis, E. and Marsili, O. (2006) Survivor: The Role of
Innovation in Firms’ Survival. Research Policy, 35,
626–41.
Charitou, C.D. and Markides, C.C. (2003)
Responses to Disruptive Strategic Innovation.
MIT Sloan Management Review, 44, 55–63.
Chesbrough, H.W. (2002) Environmental Influences
upon Firm Entry into New Sub-Markets: Evi-
dence from the Worldwide Hard Disk Drive
Industry Conditionally. Research Policy, 32, 659–
78.
Christensen, C.M. (1997) The Innovator’s Dilemma:
When New Technologies Cause Great Firms To Fail.
Harvard Business Press, Cambridge, MA.
Christensen, C.M. (2006) The Ongoing Process of
Building a Theory of Disruption. Journal of
Product Innovation Management, 23, 39–55.
Christensen, C.M. and Overdorf, M. (2000) Meeting
the Challenge of Disruptive Change. Harvard
Business Review, 78, 66–76.
DISRUPTIVE INNOVATION . . . IN REVERSE 87
Volume 23 Number 1 2014
© 2013 John Wiley & Sons Ltd
Christensen, C.M. and Raynor, E.M. (2003) The Inn-
ovator’s
Solution
: Creating and Sustaining Successful
Growth. Harvard Business Press, Cambridge, MA.
Christensen, C.M., Bohmer, R. and Kenagy, J. (2000)
Will Disruptive Innovations Cure Healthcare?
Harvard Business Review, 78, 102–12.
Christensen, C.M., Johnson, M.W. and Rigby, D.K.
(2002) Foundations for Growth. MIT Sloan Man-
agement Review, 43, 22–31.
Christensen, C.M., Baumann, H., Ruggles, R. and
Sadtler, T.M. (2006) Disruptive Innovation for
Social Change. Harvard Business Review, 84,
94–101.
Corsi, S. and Di Minin, A. (2012) Cina: Da Mercato
Emergente a Nuovo Hub di Innovazione? Mondo
Cinese, 150, 80–87.
Corso, M. and Pellegrini, L. (2007) Continuous
and Discontinuous Innovation: Overcoming the
Innovator Dilemma. Creativity and Innovation
Management, 16, 333–47.
Danneels, E. (2004) Disruptive Technology Recon-
sidered: A Critique and Research Agenda. The
Journal of Product Innovation Management, 21,
246–58.
Danneels, E. (2006) Dialogue on the effects of dis-
ruptive technology on firms and industries.
Journal of Product Innovation Management, 23,
2–4.
Di Minin, A. and Bianchi, M. (2011) Safe Nests
in Global Nets: Internationalization and
Appropriability of R&D in Wireless Telecom.
Journal of International Business Studies, 42,
910–34.
Garrette, B. and Karnani, A. (2010) Challenges in
Marketing Socially Useful Goods to the Poor.
California Management Review, 52, 29–47.
Gassmann, O. and Han, Z. (2004) Motivations and
Barriers of Foreign R&D Activities in China. R&D
Management, 34, 423–37.
Gilbert, C. (2003) The Disruption Opportunity. MIT
Sloan Management Review, 44, 27–32.
Gilbert, C. and Bower, J.L. (2002) Disruptive
Change. Harvard Business Review, 80, 95–100.
Gino, F. and Staats, B.R. (2012) The Microwork Solu-
tion. Harvard Business Review, 90, 92–6.
Glazer, R. (2007) Meta-Technologies and Innovation
Leadership: Why There May Be Nothing New
Under the Sun. California Management Review, 50,
120–43.
Govindarajan, V. (2009) The Case for ‘Reverse
Innovation’ Now. BusinessWeek Online, 26
October.
Govindarajan, V. (2012) A Reverse-Innovation Play-
book. Harvard Business Review, 90, 120–4.
Govindarajan, V. and Trimble, C. (2009) Is Reverse
Innovation Like Disruptive Innovation? Harvard
Business Review Blog Network [WWW docu-
ment]. URL http://blogs.hbr.org/hbr/hbr-now/
2009/09/is-reverse-innovation-like-dis.html
[accessed on 14 June 2012).
Govindarajan, V. and Trimble, C. (2012) Reverse
Innovation: Create Far from Home, Win Everywhere.
Harvard Business Press, Cambridge, MA.
Govindarajan, V. and Kopalle, P.K. (2006a) Disrup-
tiveness of Innovations: Measurement and an
Assessment of Reliability and Validity. Strategic
Management Journal, 27, 189–99.
Govindarajan, V. and Kopalle, P.K. (2006b) The Use-
fulness of Measuring Disruptivenes s of Innova-
tions. Ex post in Making ex ante Predictions.
Journal of Product Innovation Management, 23,
12–18.
Govindarajan, V. and Ramamurti, R. (2011) Reverse
Innovation, Emerging Markets and Global Strat-
egy. Global Strategy Journal, 1, 191–205.
Govindarajan, V., Kopalle, P.K. and Danneels, E.
(2011) The Effects of Mainstream and Emerging
Customer Orientations on Radical and Disrup-
tive Innovations. Journal of Product Innovation
Management, 1, 121–32.
Hang, C., Chen, J. and Subramanian, A.M. (2010)
Developing Disruptive Products for Emerging
Economies: Lessons from Asian Cases. Research
Technology Management, 53, 21–26.
Hart, S.L. and Christensen, C.M (2002) The Great
Leap. Driving Innovation from the Base of
the Pyramid. MIT Sloan Management Review, 44,
51–6.
Henderson, R. (2006) The Innovator’s Dilemma as a
Problem of Organizational Competence. Journal
of Product Innovation Management, 23, 5–11.
Immelt, J.R., Govindarajan, V. and Trimble, C. (2009)
How GE is Disrupting Itself. Harvard Business
Review, 87, 56–65.
Johnson, M.W, Christensen, C.M. and Kagermann,
H. (2008) Reinventing your Business Model.
Harvard Business Review, 86, 50–9.
Johnson, W. (2012) Disrupt Yourself. Harvard Busi-
ness Review, 90, 147–50.
Kanter, R.M. (2010) Block-by-Blockbuster Innova-
tion. Harvard Business Review, 88, 38.
Karamchandani, A., Kubzansky, M. and Lalwani,
N. (2011) Is the Bottom of the Pyramid Really for
You? Harvard Business Review, 89, 107–11.
Karnani, A. (2007) The Mirage of Marketing to the
Bottom of the Pyramid: How the Private Sector
Can Help Alleviate Poverty. California Manage-
ment Review, 49, 90–111.
Kassicieh, S.K., Kirchhoff, B.A., Walsh, S.T. and
McWhorter, P.J. (2002) The Role of Small Firms in
the Transfer of Disruptive Technologies.
Technovation, 22, 667–74.
Kenney, M., Massini, S. and Murtha, T.P. (2009)
Offshoring Administrative and Technical Work:
New Fields for Understanding the Global Enter-
prise. Journal of International Business Studies, 40,
887–900.
Keupp, M.M., Beckenbauer, A. and Gassmann, O.
(2009) How Managers Protect Intellectual Prop-
erty Rights in China Using de facto Strategies.
R&D Management, 39, 211–23.
London, T. and Hart, S.L. (2004) Reinventing Strat-
egies for Emerging Markets: Beyond the Transna-
tional Model. Journal of International Business
Studies, 35, 350–70.
Long, G. (2005) China’s Policies on FDI: Review
and Evaluation. In Moran, T., Graham, E.M.
and Blomstrom, M. (eds.), Does Foreign Direct
Investment Promote Development? Institute for
International Economics, Centre for Global
Development, Washington, DC, pp. 315–36.
Mangelsdorf, M.E. (2009) Good Days for
Disruptors. MIT Sloan Management Review, 50,
67–70.
88 CREATIVITY AND INNOVATION MANAGEMENT
Volume 23 Number 1 2014
© 2013 John Wiley & Sons Ltd
Markides, C. (2006) Disruptive Innovation: In Need
of Better Theory. Journal of Product Innovation
Management, 23, 19–25.
Markides, C.C. (2012) How Disruptive Will Innova-
tions from Emerging Markets Be? MIT Sloan Man-
agement Review, 54, 23–25.
Morris, H., Harvey, C. and Kelly, A. (2009) Journal
Rankings and the ABS Journal Quality Guide.
Management Decision, 47, 1441–51.
O’Reilly III, C.A. and Tushman, M. (2004) The
Ambidextrous Organization. Harvard Business
Review, 82, 74–81.
Olsen, M. and Boxembaum, E. (2009) Bottom of the
Pyramid: Organization Barriers to Implementa-
tion. California Management Review, 51, 100–25.
Patel, P. and Pavitt, K. (1991) Large Firms in the
Production of the World’s Technology – An
Important Case of Non-Globalization. Journal of
International Business Studies, 22, 1–21.
Pilkington, A., Dyerson, R. and Tissier, O. (2002)
The Electric Vehicle: Patent Data as Indicators of
Technological Development. World Patent Infor-
mation, 24, 5–12.
Prahalad, C.K. (2004) The Fortune at the Bottom of the
Pyramid. Eradicating Poverty through Profits.
Pearson Education, Harlow.
Prahalad, C.K. (2012) Bottom of the Pyramid as a
Source of Breakthrough Innovation. Journal of
Product Innovation Management, 29, 6–12.
Prahalad, C.K. and Hammond, A. (2002) Serving
the World’s Poor, Profitably. Harvard Business
Review, 80, 48–57.
Prahalad, C.K. and Hart, S.L. (2002) The Fortune at
the Bottom of the Pyramid. Strategy + Business, 26,
54–67.
Quan, X. and Chesbrough, H.W. (2010) Hierarchical
Segmentation of R&D Process and Intellectual
Property Protection: Evidence from Multinational
R&D Laboratories in China. IEEE Transactions on
Engineering Management, 57, 9–21.
Rafii, F. and Kampas, P.J. (2002) How to Identify
your Enemies before they Destroy you. Harvard
Business Review, 80, 115–23.
Rangan, V.K., Chu, M. and Petkoski, D. (2011) Seg-
menting the Base of the Pyramid. Harvard Busi-
ness Review, 89, 113–17.
Ray, S. and Ray, P.K. (2011) Product Innovation for
the People’s Car in an Emerging Economy.
Technovation, 31, 216–27.
Sandström, C., Magnusson, M. and Jörnmark, J.
(2009) Exploring Factors Influencing Incumbents’
Response to Disruptive Innovation. Creativity and
Innovation Management, 18, 8–15.
Schanz, C., Hüsig, S., Dowling, M. and Gerybadze,
A. (2011) ‘Low-Cost High-Tech’ Innovations for
China: Why Setting up a Separate R&D Unit is not
Always the Best Approach. R&D Management, 41,
307–17.
Schmidt, G.M. and Druehl, C.T. (2008) When is a
Disruptive Innovation Disruptive? Journal of
Product Innovation Management, 25, 347–69.
Seelos, C. and Mair, J. (2007) Profitable Business
Models and Market Creation in the Context of
Deep Poverty: A Strategic View. Academy of Man-
agement Perspectives, 21, 49–63.
Seely Brown, J. and Hagel III, J. (2005) Inno-
vation Blowback: Disruptive Management
Practices from Asia. The McKinsey Quarterly, 1,
34–45.
Simanis, E. (2012) Reality Check at the Bottom of the
Pyramid. Harvard Business Review, 90, 120–5.
Simanis, E. and Hart, S. (2009) Innovation from the
Inside Out. MIT Sloan Management Review, 50,
77–86.
Suzuki, J. and Kodama, F. (2004) Technological
Diversity of Persistent Innovators in Japan: Two
Case Studies of Large Japanese Firms. Research
Policy, 33, 531–49.
Utterback, J.M. (2004) The Dynamics of
Innovation. Educause Review, January–February,
42–51.
Utterback, J.M. and Acee, H.J. (2005) Disruptive
Technologies: An Expanded View. International
Journal of Innovation Management, 9, 1–17.
Vernon, R. (1966) International Investment and
International Trade in the Product Cycle. Quar-
terly Journal of Economics, 80, 190–207.
Von Zedtwitz, M. (2004) Managing Foreign R&D
Laboratories in China. R&D Management, 34, 439–
52.
Walsh, S.T., Kirchhoff, B.A. and Newbert, S. (2002)
Differentiating Market Strategies for Disruptive
Technologies. IEEE Transaction on Engineering
Management, 49, 341–51.
Williamson, P.J. (2010) Cost Innovation: Preparing
for a ‘Value-for-Money’ Revolution. Long Range
Planning, 43, 343–53.
Williamson, P.J. and Zeng, M. (2004) Strategies for
Competing in a Changed China. MIT Sloan Man-
agement Review, 45, 85–91.
Williamson, P.J. and Zeng, M. (2009) Value-for-
Money Strategies for Recessionary Times.
Harvard Business Review, 87, 66–74.
Wood, R.C. and Hamel, G. (2002) The World Bank’s
Innovation Market. Harvard Business Review, 80,
104–13.
Yu, D. and Hang, C.C. (2010) A Reflective Review of
Disruptive Innovation Theory. International
Journal of Management Reviews, 12, 435–52.
Yu, D. and Hang, C.C. (2011) Creating Technology
Candidates for Disruptive Innovation: Generally
Applicable R&D Strategies. Technovation, 31, 401–
10.
Zeng, M. and Williamson, P.J. (2007) Dragons at your
Door: How Chinese Cost Innovation is Disrupting the
Rules of Global Competition. Harvard Business
School Press, Boston, MA.
Zhao, M. (2006) Conducting R&D in Countries with
Weak Intellectual Property Rights Protection.
Management Science, 52, 1185–99.
DISRUPTIVE INNOVATION . . . IN REVERSE 89
Volume 23 Number 1 2014
© 2013 John Wiley & Sons Ltd
Simone Corsi ([email protected]) is a post-
doctoral researcher at the Institute of Man-
agement at the Scuola Superiore Sant’Anna,
Pisa, Italy. He has a PhD in Management
from the same institution. His research
focuses on foreign R&D investment in
emerging economies and reverse innova-
tion. Simone was one of the 2009 recipients
of the Associazione Toscana Cina Insieme
Fellowship for his Masters dissertation
(‘Relationship Marketing in Chinese Busi-
ness to Business’) on Italian investment in
China, and he has been Visiting Doctoral
student at the Research Center for Global
R&D Management at Tongji University,
Shanghai. His research interests also
include open innovation and disruptive
innovation.
Alberto Di Minin is an assistant professor
at Scuola Superiore Sant’Anna, Pisa, Italy,
and Research Fellow at the Berkeley
Roundtable on the International Economy
(BRIE). He has a PhD from University of
California Berkeley. Alberto works with the
Istituto di Management at Sant’Anna, and
he is an instructor at the Executive School,
International School of Advanced Educa-
tion (SIAF). His research deals with the
appropriability of innovation. He focuses
on open innovation, business models, tech-
nology transfer, intellectual property and
R&D management. On these topics he has
published widely in international journals
such as Research Policy, California Manage-
ment Review, R&D Management and Journal
of International Business Studies.
Appendix A
For our literature review, we used the following procedure.
Relying on the Academic Journal
Quality Guide (Version 4, 2010) of the Association of Business
Schools (Morris, Harvey & Kelly,
2009), we selected Grade Four and Three journals from the
following management fields: General
Management, International Business, and Innovation (see below
for a list of the selected journals).
We searched over these journals for papers whose abstracts
contained at least one of the following
keywords: disruptive innovation, reverse innovation, cost
innovation, bottom of the pyramid. We
excluded from the resulting articles book reviews and articles
whose abstracts contained words
composing the keywords put in a different order (hence meaning
a different thing).
General Management International Business Innovation
Academy of Management Review, Academy
of Management Journal, Administrative
Science Quarterly, Journal of
Management, Journal of Management
Studies, Harvard Business Review,
British Journal of Management,
California Management Review, MIT
Sloan Management Review,
International Journal of Management
Reviews, Academy of Management
Perspectives, Journal of Management
Inquiry
Journal of International
Business Studies,
International Business
Review, Management
International Review
Journal of Product
Innovation Management,
R&D Management,
Technovation
The search resulted in 44 total papers.
Given the novelty of the topic of innovation from emerging
economies, such a low number and
concentration of papers in a very limited number of journals is
not a surprise. (The papers
appeared mainly in practitioner-oriented journals and two
innovation management journals.
Furthermore, the majority of papers refer to disruptive
innovation.) As a further effort, we ran a
search using the same keywords over Google Scholar to
increase our literature base and especially
looking for practical examples. The number of papers grew to
65. The literature we relied on for
this paper is schematized in Table 1.
90 CREATIVITY AND INNOVATION MANAGEMENT
Volume 23 Number 1 2014
© 2013 John Wiley & Sons Ltd
Copyright of Creativity & Innovation Management is the
property of Wiley-Blackwell and its
content may not be copied or emailed to multiple sites or posted
to a listserv without the
copyright holder's express written permission. However, users
may print, download, or email
articles for individual use.
Australasian Accounting, Business and Finance
Journal
Volume 1 Australasian Accounting Business and
Finance Journal
Issue 2 Australasian Accounting Business and Finance
Journal
Article 3
Breaking the Paradox of Innovation in Small
Businesses through Sustaining and Disruptive
Reinvention
V. Baard
Australian Catholic University
T. Watts
University of Wollongong, [email protected]
Follow this and additional works at: http://ro.uow.edu.au/aabfj
Copyright ©2007 Australasian Accounting Business and
Finance Journal and Authors.
Research Online is the open access institutional repository for
the University of Wollongong. For further information contact
the UOW Library:
[email protected]
Recommended Citation
Baard, V. and Watts, T., Breaking the Paradox of Innovation in
Small Businesses through Sustaining
and Disruptive Reinvention, Australasian Accounting , Business
and Finance Journal, 1(2), 2007.
http://ro.uow.edu.au/?utm_source=ro.uow.edu.au%2Faabfj%2Fv
ol1%2Fiss2%2F3&utm_medium=PDF&utm_campaign=PDFCov
erPages
http://ro.uow.edu.au/?utm_source=ro.uow.edu.au%2Faabfj%2Fv
ol1%2Fiss2%2F3&utm_medium=PDF&utm_campaign=PDFCov
erPages
http://ro.uow.edu.au/aabfj?utm_source=ro.uow.edu.au%2Faabfj
%2Fvol1%2Fiss2%2F3&utm_medium=PDF&utm_campaign=PD
FCoverPages
http://ro.uow.edu.au/aabfj?utm_source=ro.uow.edu.au%2Faabfj
%2Fvol1%2Fiss2%2F3&utm_medium=PDF&utm_campaign=PD
FCoverPages
http://ro.uow.edu.au/aabfj/vol1?utm_source=ro.uow.edu.au%2F
aabfj%2Fvol1%2Fiss2%2F3&utm_medium=PDF&utm_campaig
n=PDFCoverPages
http://ro.uow.edu.au/aabfj/vol1?utm_source=ro.uow.edu.au%2F
aabfj%2Fvol1%2Fiss2%2F3&utm_medium=PDF&utm_campaig
n=PDFCoverPages
http://ro.uow.edu.au/aabfj/vol1/iss2?utm_source=ro.uow.edu.au
%2Faabfj%2Fvol1%2Fiss2%2F3&utm_medium=PDF&utm_cam
paign=PDFCoverPages
http://ro.uow.edu.au/aabfj/vol1/iss2?utm_source=ro.uow.edu.au
%2Faabfj%2Fvol1%2Fiss2%2F3&utm_medium=PDF&utm_cam
paign=PDFCoverPages
http://ro.uow.edu.au/aabfj/vol1/iss2/3?utm_source=ro.uow.edu.a
u%2Faabfj%2Fvol1%2Fiss2%2F3&utm_medium=PDF&utm_ca
mpaign=PDFCoverPages
http://ro.uow.edu.au/aabfj?utm_source=ro.uow.edu.au%2Faabfj
%2Fvol1%2Fiss2%2F3&utm_medium=PDF&utm_campaign=PD
FCoverPages
Breaking the Paradox of Innovation in Small Businesses through
Sustaining
and Disruptive Reinvention
Abstract
In 2005 Deloitte Research released a paper examining the
phenomenon they refer to as the ‘innovation
paradox’: the inability or reluctance of manufacturing firms to
pursue strategies that build the operational
capabilities necessary for innovation that will provide both
profitability and growth. The report claims that
this is due to the rapidly increasing complexity of global
markets and the lack of synchronising innovation
efforts across their value chain, thus positioning the problem as
an important contemporary issue. While the
research did not specifically target small and medium
enterprises, the implications for this business sector are
considerable given their substantial contribution to global
economies and their high failure rates in the first
three to five years of operation. While not questioning the data
in the Deloitte research, this paper does
question the assumption that the phenomenon is irreversible and
the apparent underlying self-fulfilling
prophecy with respect to small to medium enterprises. To
demonstrate this the authors draw on a case study
of a small manufacturing company in rural New South Wales,
Australia, which operated between 1889 and
1983, to show that the breaking of the innovation paradox was
successfully achieved by this firm in the late
nineteenth and early twentieth century. Applying the case study
to the Deloitte model the study demonstrates
contemporary similarities by overlaying the Laycock history on
the successes / failures identified by Deloitte.
This article is available in Australasian Accounting, Business
and Finance Journal: http://ro.uow.edu.au/aabfj/vol1/iss2/3
http://ro.uow.edu.au/aabfj/vol1/iss2/3?utm_source=ro.uow.edu.a
u%2Faabfj%2Fvol1%2Fiss2%2F3&utm_medium=PDF&utm_ca
mpaign=PDFCoverPages
The Australasian Accounting Business & Finance Journal, May,
2007
Baard and Watts: Breaking the Paradox. Vol. 1, No.2.
25
Breaking the Paradox of Innovation in Small Businesses through
Sustaining and Disruptive Reinvention
Dr Vicki Baard
Discipline of Accounting and Finance, School of Business and
Informatics, Australian Catholic University
Dr Ted Watts†
Discipline of Accounting, School of Accounting and Finance,
University of Wollongong
ABSTRACT
In 2005 Deloitte Research released a paper examining the
phenomenon they refer to as
the ‘innovation paradox’: the inability or reluctance of
manufacturing firms to pursue
strategies that build the operational capabilities necessary for
innovation that will
provide both profitability and growth. The report claims that
this is due to the rapidly
increasing complexity of global markets and the lack of
synchronising innovation efforts
across their value chain, thus positioning the problem as an
important contemporary
issue. While the research did not specifically target small and
medium enterprises, the
implications for this business sector are considerable given their
substantial contribution
to global economies and their high failure rates in the first three
to five years of
operation. While not questioning the data in the Deloitte
research, this paper does
question the assumption that the phenomenon is irreversible and
the apparent
underlying self-fulfilling prophecy with respect to small to
medium enterprises. To
demonstrate this the authors draw on a case study of a small
manufacturing company in
rural New South Wales, Australia, which operated between 1889
and 1983, to show that
the breaking of the innovation paradox was successfully
achieved by this firm in the late
nineteenth and early twentieth century. Applying the case study
to the Deloitte model
the study demonstrates contemporary similarities by overlaying
the Laycock history on
the successes / failures identified by Deloitte.
Key words: Small business innovation, reinvention, innovation
paradox
† Corresponding author. Mail: Building 40. School of
Accounting & Finance, University of Wollongong. E-mail:
[email protected]
* The authors would like to thank the participants of the
Emerging Issues in International Accounting
Conference for their helpful comments in the development of
this paper. The authors retain all responsibility for
the arguments presented and their potential errors.
INTRODUCTION
Deloitte (2005) describes the innovation paradox as the inability
or reluctance of
manufacturing firms to pursue strategies that build the
operational capabilities necessary for
innovation to provide both profitability and growth. Their
research shows that innovation was
the top factor with respect to growth, but the bottom factor with
respect to supply chain
management. They claim that this is due to the rapidly
increasing complexity of global
markets and value chains, thus positioning the problem as a
contemporary phenomenon.
Relating this specifically to small business renowned for
innovation, this paper questions the
assumptions that this is a contemporary phenomenon and is a
self- fulfilling prophecy. To
demonstrate this the authors draw on a case study of a small
manufacturing company in rural
The Australasian Accounting Business & Finance Journal, May,
2007
Baard and Watts: Breaking the Paradox. Vol. 1, No.2.
26
New South Wales, Australia, which operated between 1889 and
1983, to show that the
breaking of the innovation paradox was successfully achieved
by this firm in the late
nineteenth and early twentieth centuries. Applying the case
study of Joseph Laycock and Son
(Gibson, 1988) to the Deloitte model the study demonstrates
contemporary similarities by
overlaying the Laycock history on the successes / failures
identified by Deloitte. In this way
the study demonstrates that by continually reinventing itsel f,
this firm successfully avoided
the paradox of innovation.
THE DELOITTE MODEL
The Deloitte model is premised on four critical outcomes of
their research. First, that
manufacturers must master the complexity of innovation in
order to grow; second, that such
innovation is driven by changing customer demands and
competitive offerings; third, the need
to develop a value chain that builds effectively on the market
complexities; and finally, the
effective management of the entire product lifecycle. From
these outcomes Deloitte identified
three decisive steps that can be used to generate profitable
growth through innovation.
The first is the task of creating innovation, the act of generating
and evaluating ideas. This
involves generating ideas or sourcing concepts from outside the
organisation, developing
business strategies on which to base investment decisions,
recognising and understanding the
gap between the performance of existing products that satisfy
customer demands and
proposed new products, and determining the most appropriate
organisational model to put the
innovation into practice.
The second step is to exploit the innovations created in step
one. This involves maximising
the innovations growth and profit throughout the product’s
entire lifecycle. In particular,
ensuring profitability of the product through flexibility of
design, thus allowing speedy and
inexpensive modifications, together with cost-effective service
and other downstream
activities. In other words, the business must recognise the enti re
value chain.
Building innovation capabilities for success is the third step.
This involves identification and
utilisation of four key factors:
• better visibility, both upstream and downstream in the value
chain
• flexibility in product designs and platforms that allow for
quick modifications of
product offerings to meet market demands
• more extensive collaboration with customers to define product
requirements, and
with suppliers to design components and new materials
• the use of advanced technologies for product lifecycle
management, product data
management, customer relations management, and advanced
planning and
scheduling.
LITERATURE REVIEW
INTRODUCTION
Innovation is defined as an application of ideas and knowledge
to meet current or future
market needs or, more specifically, as the ability of a firm to
develop a product to satisfy the
future needs of customers (Fitzgerald and Moon, 1996). The
difference, while subtle, shifts
the focus from market needs to customer needs, and
simultaneously from business in general
to small business specifically. This is significant because small
business innovations in the
nineteenth and twentieth centuries have outnumbered big
business by two to one (Siropolis,
1997). This is mainly due to the ability of small business to
concentrate on new products,
The Australasian Accounting Business & Finance Journal, May,
2007
Baard and Watts: Breaking the Paradox. Vol. 1, No.2.
27
rather than improving existing products, as is generally the case
with big business (Hatten,
2006). While the high failure rate of small businesses is well
documented small business have
often survived, and indeed flourished, through the process of
‘creative destruction’ or
‘disruptive reinvention’, which constitutes the replacement of
existing products, processes
and ideas, and of businesses with new and better ones (Hatten,
2006).
SUSTAINING AND DISRUPTIVE REINVENTION
Fasenfest and Jacobs (2003) document the case of the
automotive industry in southeast
Michigan, where a rapidly declining manufacturing sector,
overly dependent on one sector of
industrial production, transformed itself into a revitalised and
restructured high-technology
business centre. This transformation of a small business sector
represented a shift away from
manufacturing centres to technical centres that design and build
prototypes, make dies,
fixtures and machine tools, and assemble automobiles.
Similarly, the small businesses of
Richmond, Virginia reinvented themselves from support
businesses for the traditional
banking, tobacco and manufacturing industries to dynamic
players in the information
technology, semiconductor and biotech industries (Mosher,
2000).
The two examples cited above are examples of the changing
small business landscape during
the Twentieth century, and demonstrate the need for sustainable
competitive advantage
through reinvention based on disruptive innovation. According
to Voelpel, Leibold and Tekie
(2004), the focus is on the development of new bases of
building strategic competitive
advantage in order to outperform competitors and leapfrog into
new areas of competitive
advantage. However, the strategy of reinvention for small
businesses predates the Twentieth
century. For example Morgenthaler (1989) reports the case of
the Warren Feathbone Co.
between 1883 and 1989 and its strategic reinvention. The
company, established in 1883,
manufactured an elastic boning material from finely split turkey
quills, which was used to
stiffen and shape corsets, collars and bustles in the ladies
clothing industry. However, the
company fell victim to changing fashions and the development
of plastics and, in 1938,
reinvented itself, in collaboration with the B.F. Goodrich Co.,
into a manufacturer of plastic
baby pants. Its second reinvention occurred in the late 1960s
and early 1970s, when the era of
disposable nappies arrived, reducing the use of cloth nappies,
upon which the company relied.
This reinvention saw the emergence of a manufacturer of baby
clothes, a small thriving
business that still exists.
The impetus for reinvention is driven by factors within the firm
or from the industry of which
the firm is part of (Burns, 2001). Such factors include new
knowledge (both scientific and
non-scientific), the unexpected (unexpected success or failure,
or an unexpected event), and
changes in perception which might be caused by economic
changes, together with societal,
cultural and fashion changes. All of these are evident in the
cases reviewed above.
STRUCTURE OF THE FIRM
The above review of reinvention shows that innovative
behaviour is influenced by a variety of
forces, including the business activity, the industry and the type
and structure of the company.
Baard (2002) argues that in small businesses the focus of the
organising activity is the
achievement of an effective and efficient blend of the essential
ingredients for organisational
success, specifically: people, physical resources and structure.
In this respect small businesses
have a characteristically flat, flexible structure (Hudson, Smart
and Bourne, 2001) comprised
of one hierarchical level (Hankinson, Bartlett and Ducheneaut,
1997).
The other aspect of structure that appears in both the
automobile industry study (Fasenfest and
Jacobs, 2003) and the Warren Featherbone study (Morgenthaler,
1989) is the strong
The Australasian Accounting Business & Finance Journal, May,
2007
Baard and Watts: Breaking the Paradox. Vol. 1, No.2.
28
relationship between changes in structure and the timing of
reinvention. The reinventions of
the automobile industry between the 1970s and the 1990s
corresponded with important shifts
in the development of human capital strategies, including the
flattening of the organisation,
the transformation from unionised to non-unionised firms, and
the replacement of existing
management with a more highly educated management team.
Likewise, with the Warren
Featherbone case, the major innovation reinventions within the
company corresponded with
generational changes in management. The move into plastic
nappies in 1923 occurred with
the retirement of the 86 year old founder. This was followed, in
1956, by the firm’s move
from Michigan to Georgia, and into general clothing
manufacturing, with the founder’s
grandson taking control of the business. This was followed in
1976 with the decision by the
new vice-president, the founder’s great-grandson, to discontinue
the manufacture of general
clothing and the move into the manufacture of medium-priced
specialist baby clothes.
This review, while brief, suggests that small business can adopt
competitive strategies that
build on its operational capabilities. This is displayed through
the firms ability to reinvent
itself, and by so doing avoid the paradox of innovation.
OVERLAYING THE LAYCOCK STORY
BACKGROUND
The Laycock story is documented by Gibson (1988) in his thesis
Joseph Laycock and Son –
Blacksmiths, Engineers and Manufactures 1889-1983, and much
of the information is drawn
from this work. Joseph Laycock and Son commenced operations
in Bathurst, a rural
community in Western New South Wales, Australia, in 1889 as
a blacksmith’s shop,
progressively diversifying into engineering, founding, welding
and, in 1918, the manufacture
of bagged goods elevators and conveyors for the agricultural
industry. With the success of the
Laycock Elevator, the company turned to the manufacture of
fruit pickers and other small
farm equipment, including the patenting and manufacture of a
combined cutting and threshing
machine in 1922.
Following the abolition of bag stacks in favour of bulk grain
storage in the 1960s, the viability
of chain-type elevators declined, and the Laycock Company
ceased elevator production in
1969. However, the other components, such as the light
engineering section, expanded, and
with the garage, continued until the death of Joe Laycock in
1986 and the closure of the
company.
CREATING INNOVATION
According to the Deloitte (2005, p 9) paper,
…manufacturers that are superior at product innovation make it
a formal,
centralised, step-by-step business process, not a haphazardly
122820211Chapter Two Defining Crimes and Measurin
122820211Chapter Two Defining Crimes and Measurin
122820211Chapter Two Defining Crimes and Measurin
122820211Chapter Two Defining Crimes and Measurin
122820211Chapter Two Defining Crimes and Measurin
122820211Chapter Two Defining Crimes and Measurin
122820211Chapter Two Defining Crimes and Measurin
122820211Chapter Two Defining Crimes and Measurin
122820211Chapter Two Defining Crimes and Measurin
122820211Chapter Two Defining Crimes and Measurin
122820211Chapter Two Defining Crimes and Measurin
122820211Chapter Two Defining Crimes and Measurin
122820211Chapter Two Defining Crimes and Measurin
122820211Chapter Two Defining Crimes and Measurin
122820211Chapter Two Defining Crimes and Measurin
122820211Chapter Two Defining Crimes and Measurin
122820211Chapter Two Defining Crimes and Measurin
122820211Chapter Two Defining Crimes and Measurin
122820211Chapter Two Defining Crimes and Measurin
122820211Chapter Two Defining Crimes and Measurin
122820211Chapter Two Defining Crimes and Measurin
122820211Chapter Two Defining Crimes and Measurin
122820211Chapter Two Defining Crimes and Measurin
122820211Chapter Two Defining Crimes and Measurin
122820211Chapter Two Defining Crimes and Measurin
122820211Chapter Two Defining Crimes and Measurin
122820211Chapter Two Defining Crimes and Measurin
122820211Chapter Two Defining Crimes and Measurin
122820211Chapter Two Defining Crimes and Measurin
122820211Chapter Two Defining Crimes and Measurin
122820211Chapter Two Defining Crimes and Measurin
122820211Chapter Two Defining Crimes and Measurin
122820211Chapter Two Defining Crimes and Measurin
122820211Chapter Two Defining Crimes and Measurin
122820211Chapter Two Defining Crimes and Measurin
122820211Chapter Two Defining Crimes and Measurin
122820211Chapter Two Defining Crimes and Measurin
122820211Chapter Two Defining Crimes and Measurin
122820211Chapter Two Defining Crimes and Measurin
122820211Chapter Two Defining Crimes and Measurin
122820211Chapter Two Defining Crimes and Measurin
122820211Chapter Two Defining Crimes and Measurin
122820211Chapter Two Defining Crimes and Measurin
122820211Chapter Two Defining Crimes and Measurin
122820211Chapter Two Defining Crimes and Measurin
122820211Chapter Two Defining Crimes and Measurin
122820211Chapter Two Defining Crimes and Measurin
122820211Chapter Two Defining Crimes and Measurin
122820211Chapter Two Defining Crimes and Measurin
122820211Chapter Two Defining Crimes and Measurin
122820211Chapter Two Defining Crimes and Measurin
122820211Chapter Two Defining Crimes and Measurin
122820211Chapter Two Defining Crimes and Measurin
122820211Chapter Two Defining Crimes and Measurin
122820211Chapter Two Defining Crimes and Measurin
122820211Chapter Two Defining Crimes and Measurin
122820211Chapter Two Defining Crimes and Measurin
122820211Chapter Two Defining Crimes and Measurin
122820211Chapter Two Defining Crimes and Measurin
122820211Chapter Two Defining Crimes and Measurin
122820211Chapter Two Defining Crimes and Measurin
122820211Chapter Two Defining Crimes and Measurin
122820211Chapter Two Defining Crimes and Measurin
122820211Chapter Two Defining Crimes and Measurin
122820211Chapter Two Defining Crimes and Measurin
122820211Chapter Two Defining Crimes and Measurin
122820211Chapter Two Defining Crimes and Measurin
122820211Chapter Two Defining Crimes and Measurin
122820211Chapter Two Defining Crimes and Measurin
122820211Chapter Two Defining Crimes and Measurin
122820211Chapter Two Defining Crimes and Measurin
122820211Chapter Two Defining Crimes and Measurin
122820211Chapter Two Defining Crimes and Measurin
122820211Chapter Two Defining Crimes and Measurin
122820211Chapter Two Defining Crimes and Measurin
122820211Chapter Two Defining Crimes and Measurin
122820211Chapter Two Defining Crimes and Measurin
122820211Chapter Two Defining Crimes and Measurin
122820211Chapter Two Defining Crimes and Measurin
122820211Chapter Two Defining Crimes and Measurin
122820211Chapter Two Defining Crimes and Measurin
122820211Chapter Two Defining Crimes and Measurin
122820211Chapter Two Defining Crimes and Measurin
122820211Chapter Two Defining Crimes and Measurin
122820211Chapter Two Defining Crimes and Measurin
122820211Chapter Two Defining Crimes and Measurin
122820211Chapter Two Defining Crimes and Measurin
122820211Chapter Two Defining Crimes and Measurin
122820211Chapter Two Defining Crimes and Measurin
122820211Chapter Two Defining Crimes and Measurin
122820211Chapter Two Defining Crimes and Measurin
122820211Chapter Two Defining Crimes and Measurin
122820211Chapter Two Defining Crimes and Measurin
122820211Chapter Two Defining Crimes and Measurin
122820211Chapter Two Defining Crimes and Measurin
122820211Chapter Two Defining Crimes and Measurin
122820211Chapter Two Defining Crimes and Measurin
122820211Chapter Two Defining Crimes and Measurin
122820211Chapter Two Defining Crimes and Measurin
122820211Chapter Two Defining Crimes and Measurin
122820211Chapter Two Defining Crimes and Measurin
122820211Chapter Two Defining Crimes and Measurin
122820211Chapter Two Defining Crimes and Measurin
122820211Chapter Two Defining Crimes and Measurin
122820211Chapter Two Defining Crimes and Measurin
122820211Chapter Two Defining Crimes and Measurin
122820211Chapter Two Defining Crimes and Measurin
122820211Chapter Two Defining Crimes and Measurin
122820211Chapter Two Defining Crimes and Measurin
122820211Chapter Two Defining Crimes and Measurin
122820211Chapter Two Defining Crimes and Measurin
122820211Chapter Two Defining Crimes and Measurin
122820211Chapter Two Defining Crimes and Measurin
122820211Chapter Two Defining Crimes and Measurin
122820211Chapter Two Defining Crimes and Measurin
122820211Chapter Two Defining Crimes and Measurin
122820211Chapter Two Defining Crimes and Measurin
122820211Chapter Two Defining Crimes and Measurin
122820211Chapter Two Defining Crimes and Measurin
122820211Chapter Two Defining Crimes and Measurin
122820211Chapter Two Defining Crimes and Measurin
122820211Chapter Two Defining Crimes and Measurin
122820211Chapter Two Defining Crimes and Measurin
122820211Chapter Two Defining Crimes and Measurin
122820211Chapter Two Defining Crimes and Measurin
122820211Chapter Two Defining Crimes and Measurin
122820211Chapter Two Defining Crimes and Measurin
122820211Chapter Two Defining Crimes and Measurin
122820211Chapter Two Defining Crimes and Measurin
122820211Chapter Two Defining Crimes and Measurin

More Related Content

Similar to 122820211Chapter Two Defining Crimes and Measurin

Ethics in Criminal Data Collection
Ethics in Criminal Data CollectionEthics in Criminal Data Collection
Ethics in Criminal Data CollectionAyodele Odubela
 
11320171Chapter 13 Public Order Crimes-Slides and
11320171Chapter 13 Public Order Crimes-Slides and11320171Chapter 13 Public Order Crimes-Slides and
11320171Chapter 13 Public Order Crimes-Slides andBenitoSumpter862
 
11320171Chapter 13 Public Order Crimes-Slides and
11320171Chapter 13 Public Order Crimes-Slides and11320171Chapter 13 Public Order Crimes-Slides and
11320171Chapter 13 Public Order Crimes-Slides andSantosConleyha
 
Forensic psychology powerpoint.pdf
Forensic psychology powerpoint.pdfForensic psychology powerpoint.pdf
Forensic psychology powerpoint.pdfphweb
 
Session 3 1 lllc 2222 official statistics.2016
Session 3 1 lllc 2222 official statistics.2016Session 3 1 lllc 2222 official statistics.2016
Session 3 1 lllc 2222 official statistics.2016Nathan Loynes
 
Chapter 2 Criminology
Chapter 2 CriminologyChapter 2 Criminology
Chapter 2 CriminologyKatrina Homer
 
81-260-1 Chapter 1
81-260-1 Chapter 181-260-1 Chapter 1
81-260-1 Chapter 1mpalaro
 
81-220-1 - Chapter 2
81-220-1 - Chapter 281-220-1 - Chapter 2
81-220-1 - Chapter 2mpalaro
 
S Johnson SROP Poster_Melde (1)
S Johnson SROP Poster_Melde (1)S Johnson SROP Poster_Melde (1)
S Johnson SROP Poster_Melde (1)Shavonda Johnson
 
ThinkNow Policing Study 2020
ThinkNow Policing Study 2020 ThinkNow Policing Study 2020
ThinkNow Policing Study 2020 ThinkNow
 
Chapter 6Measuring Crime1©2018 Cengage Lear
Chapter 6Measuring Crime1©2018 Cengage LearChapter 6Measuring Crime1©2018 Cengage Lear
Chapter 6Measuring Crime1©2018 Cengage LearJinElias52
 
RACE, ETHNICITY, VICTIMIZATION, AND OFFENDINGPerception
RACE, ETHNICITY, VICTIMIZATION, AND OFFENDINGPerception RACE, ETHNICITY, VICTIMIZATION, AND OFFENDINGPerception
RACE, ETHNICITY, VICTIMIZATION, AND OFFENDINGPerception AlleneMcclendon878
 

Similar to 122820211Chapter Two Defining Crimes and Measurin (20)

Chapter12
Chapter12Chapter12
Chapter12
 
SociologyExchange.co.uk Shared Resource
SociologyExchange.co.uk Shared ResourceSociologyExchange.co.uk Shared Resource
SociologyExchange.co.uk Shared Resource
 
Ethics in Criminal Data Collection
Ethics in Criminal Data CollectionEthics in Criminal Data Collection
Ethics in Criminal Data Collection
 
11320171Chapter 13 Public Order Crimes-Slides and
11320171Chapter 13 Public Order Crimes-Slides and11320171Chapter 13 Public Order Crimes-Slides and
11320171Chapter 13 Public Order Crimes-Slides and
 
11320171Chapter 13 Public Order Crimes-Slides and
11320171Chapter 13 Public Order Crimes-Slides and11320171Chapter 13 Public Order Crimes-Slides and
11320171Chapter 13 Public Order Crimes-Slides and
 
Crime
Crime Crime
Crime
 
Forensic psychology powerpoint.pdf
Forensic psychology powerpoint.pdfForensic psychology powerpoint.pdf
Forensic psychology powerpoint.pdf
 
Chpater4
Chpater4Chpater4
Chpater4
 
Session 3 1 lllc 2222 official statistics.2016
Session 3 1 lllc 2222 official statistics.2016Session 3 1 lllc 2222 official statistics.2016
Session 3 1 lllc 2222 official statistics.2016
 
Chapter 2 Criminology
Chapter 2 CriminologyChapter 2 Criminology
Chapter 2 Criminology
 
81-260-1 Chapter 1
81-260-1 Chapter 181-260-1 Chapter 1
81-260-1 Chapter 1
 
Robert Kinscherff and Frank DiCataldo, "Half a Life: Legal and Policy Implica...
Robert Kinscherff and Frank DiCataldo, "Half a Life: Legal and Policy Implica...Robert Kinscherff and Frank DiCataldo, "Half a Life: Legal and Policy Implica...
Robert Kinscherff and Frank DiCataldo, "Half a Life: Legal and Policy Implica...
 
81-220-1 - Chapter 2
81-220-1 - Chapter 281-220-1 - Chapter 2
81-220-1 - Chapter 2
 
S Johnson SROP Poster_Melde (1)
S Johnson SROP Poster_Melde (1)S Johnson SROP Poster_Melde (1)
S Johnson SROP Poster_Melde (1)
 
Crime in the Philippines
Crime in the PhilippinesCrime in the Philippines
Crime in the Philippines
 
Youth & Organised Crime in Ciudad Juarez, Mexico
Youth & Organised Crime in Ciudad Juarez, MexicoYouth & Organised Crime in Ciudad Juarez, Mexico
Youth & Organised Crime in Ciudad Juarez, Mexico
 
ThinkNow Policing Study 2020
ThinkNow Policing Study 2020 ThinkNow Policing Study 2020
ThinkNow Policing Study 2020
 
Chapter 6Measuring Crime1©2018 Cengage Lear
Chapter 6Measuring Crime1©2018 Cengage LearChapter 6Measuring Crime1©2018 Cengage Lear
Chapter 6Measuring Crime1©2018 Cengage Lear
 
SociologyExchange.co.uk Shared Resource
SociologyExchange.co.uk Shared ResourceSociologyExchange.co.uk Shared Resource
SociologyExchange.co.uk Shared Resource
 
RACE, ETHNICITY, VICTIMIZATION, AND OFFENDINGPerception
RACE, ETHNICITY, VICTIMIZATION, AND OFFENDINGPerception RACE, ETHNICITY, VICTIMIZATION, AND OFFENDINGPerception
RACE, ETHNICITY, VICTIMIZATION, AND OFFENDINGPerception
 

More from CicelyBourqueju

123456789101112131415161
123456789101112131415161123456789101112131415161
123456789101112131415161CicelyBourqueju
 
13022 1 BIOL 315 Salmonella and Typhoid fever
13022 1 BIOL 315 Salmonella and Typhoid fever 13022 1 BIOL 315 Salmonella and Typhoid fever
13022 1 BIOL 315 Salmonella and Typhoid fever CicelyBourqueju
 
12620, 10(28 AMBritish Jury Delivers First Conviction for Fe
12620, 10(28 AMBritish Jury Delivers First Conviction for Fe12620, 10(28 AMBritish Jury Delivers First Conviction for Fe
12620, 10(28 AMBritish Jury Delivers First Conviction for FeCicelyBourqueju
 
12621, 1000 PMOriginality ReportPage 1 of 6httpsclas
12621, 1000 PMOriginality ReportPage 1 of 6httpsclas12621, 1000 PMOriginality ReportPage 1 of 6httpsclas
12621, 1000 PMOriginality ReportPage 1 of 6httpsclasCicelyBourqueju
 
1302 Notes – 06 – February 4, 2021 Writing about Fiction (&
1302 Notes – 06 – February 4, 2021 Writing about Fiction (& 1302 Notes – 06 – February 4, 2021 Writing about Fiction (&
1302 Notes – 06 – February 4, 2021 Writing about Fiction (& CicelyBourqueju
 
1255A Strengths Focus and Quality LeadershipSucc
1255A Strengths Focus and Quality LeadershipSucc1255A Strengths Focus and Quality LeadershipSucc
1255A Strengths Focus and Quality LeadershipSuccCicelyBourqueju
 
13-1 Final Project Milestone One Introduction
13-1 Final Project Milestone One Introduction13-1 Final Project Milestone One Introduction
13-1 Final Project Milestone One IntroductionCicelyBourqueju
 
13.7TearViscosityPressurePlate Gap0.00350.00180.000.000.00350.0017
13.7TearViscosityPressurePlate Gap0.00350.00180.000.000.00350.001713.7TearViscosityPressurePlate Gap0.00350.00180.000.000.00350.0017
13.7TearViscosityPressurePlate Gap0.00350.00180.000.000.00350.0017CicelyBourqueju
 
12622, 935 PM Module Four Assignment Guidelines and Rubric
12622, 935 PM Module Four Assignment Guidelines and Rubric 12622, 935 PM Module Four Assignment Guidelines and Rubric
12622, 935 PM Module Four Assignment Guidelines and Rubric CicelyBourqueju
 
123CLC Assignment COMPANY ANALYSISGro
123CLC Assignment COMPANY ANALYSISGro123CLC Assignment COMPANY ANALYSISGro
123CLC Assignment COMPANY ANALYSISGroCicelyBourqueju
 
126 Chapter IXeBay An E-Titan Success StoryZho
126  Chapter IXeBay An E-Titan Success StoryZho126  Chapter IXeBay An E-Titan Success StoryZho
126 Chapter IXeBay An E-Titan Success StoryZhoCicelyBourqueju
 
12622, 930 AM Full article Strategic Management in the Pub
12622, 930 AM Full article Strategic Management in the Pub12622, 930 AM Full article Strategic Management in the Pub
12622, 930 AM Full article Strategic Management in the PubCicelyBourqueju
 
12345678Sp.Article ErrorPV
12345678Sp.Article ErrorPV12345678Sp.Article ErrorPV
12345678Sp.Article ErrorPVCicelyBourqueju
 
13 Business and Global GovernanceMarc FudgeCase Scen
13 Business and Global GovernanceMarc FudgeCase Scen13 Business and Global GovernanceMarc FudgeCase Scen
13 Business and Global GovernanceMarc FudgeCase ScenCicelyBourqueju
 
123Pocket Guide to Quality Improvement in Healthcare
123Pocket Guide to Quality Improvement in Healthcare123Pocket Guide to Quality Improvement in Healthcare
123Pocket Guide to Quality Improvement in HealthcareCicelyBourqueju
 
13-1 IntroductionThe Galleon Group was a privately owned hedge f
13-1 IntroductionThe Galleon Group was a privately owned hedge f13-1 IntroductionThe Galleon Group was a privately owned hedge f
13-1 IntroductionThe Galleon Group was a privately owned hedge fCicelyBourqueju
 
13 Assessing Current Approaches to Childhood Immunizatio
13 Assessing Current Approaches to Childhood Immunizatio13 Assessing Current Approaches to Childhood Immunizatio
13 Assessing Current Approaches to Childhood ImmunizatioCicelyBourqueju
 
12Women Veterans Mental Healthcare
12Women Veterans Mental Healthcare12Women Veterans Mental Healthcare
12Women Veterans Mental HealthcareCicelyBourqueju
 
1234 Oak StreetComment by Author Good letter format that f
1234 Oak StreetComment by Author Good letter format that f1234 Oak StreetComment by Author Good letter format that f
1234 Oak StreetComment by Author Good letter format that fCicelyBourqueju
 
1252017PlayPositNameDate Francisco GonzalezL
1252017PlayPositNameDate Francisco GonzalezL1252017PlayPositNameDate Francisco GonzalezL
1252017PlayPositNameDate Francisco GonzalezLCicelyBourqueju
 

More from CicelyBourqueju (20)

123456789101112131415161
123456789101112131415161123456789101112131415161
123456789101112131415161
 
13022 1 BIOL 315 Salmonella and Typhoid fever
13022 1 BIOL 315 Salmonella and Typhoid fever 13022 1 BIOL 315 Salmonella and Typhoid fever
13022 1 BIOL 315 Salmonella and Typhoid fever
 
12620, 10(28 AMBritish Jury Delivers First Conviction for Fe
12620, 10(28 AMBritish Jury Delivers First Conviction for Fe12620, 10(28 AMBritish Jury Delivers First Conviction for Fe
12620, 10(28 AMBritish Jury Delivers First Conviction for Fe
 
12621, 1000 PMOriginality ReportPage 1 of 6httpsclas
12621, 1000 PMOriginality ReportPage 1 of 6httpsclas12621, 1000 PMOriginality ReportPage 1 of 6httpsclas
12621, 1000 PMOriginality ReportPage 1 of 6httpsclas
 
1302 Notes – 06 – February 4, 2021 Writing about Fiction (&
1302 Notes – 06 – February 4, 2021 Writing about Fiction (& 1302 Notes – 06 – February 4, 2021 Writing about Fiction (&
1302 Notes – 06 – February 4, 2021 Writing about Fiction (&
 
1255A Strengths Focus and Quality LeadershipSucc
1255A Strengths Focus and Quality LeadershipSucc1255A Strengths Focus and Quality LeadershipSucc
1255A Strengths Focus and Quality LeadershipSucc
 
13-1 Final Project Milestone One Introduction
13-1 Final Project Milestone One Introduction13-1 Final Project Milestone One Introduction
13-1 Final Project Milestone One Introduction
 
13.7TearViscosityPressurePlate Gap0.00350.00180.000.000.00350.0017
13.7TearViscosityPressurePlate Gap0.00350.00180.000.000.00350.001713.7TearViscosityPressurePlate Gap0.00350.00180.000.000.00350.0017
13.7TearViscosityPressurePlate Gap0.00350.00180.000.000.00350.0017
 
12622, 935 PM Module Four Assignment Guidelines and Rubric
12622, 935 PM Module Four Assignment Guidelines and Rubric 12622, 935 PM Module Four Assignment Guidelines and Rubric
12622, 935 PM Module Four Assignment Guidelines and Rubric
 
123CLC Assignment COMPANY ANALYSISGro
123CLC Assignment COMPANY ANALYSISGro123CLC Assignment COMPANY ANALYSISGro
123CLC Assignment COMPANY ANALYSISGro
 
126 Chapter IXeBay An E-Titan Success StoryZho
126  Chapter IXeBay An E-Titan Success StoryZho126  Chapter IXeBay An E-Titan Success StoryZho
126 Chapter IXeBay An E-Titan Success StoryZho
 
12622, 930 AM Full article Strategic Management in the Pub
12622, 930 AM Full article Strategic Management in the Pub12622, 930 AM Full article Strategic Management in the Pub
12622, 930 AM Full article Strategic Management in the Pub
 
12345678Sp.Article ErrorPV
12345678Sp.Article ErrorPV12345678Sp.Article ErrorPV
12345678Sp.Article ErrorPV
 
13 Business and Global GovernanceMarc FudgeCase Scen
13 Business and Global GovernanceMarc FudgeCase Scen13 Business and Global GovernanceMarc FudgeCase Scen
13 Business and Global GovernanceMarc FudgeCase Scen
 
123Pocket Guide to Quality Improvement in Healthcare
123Pocket Guide to Quality Improvement in Healthcare123Pocket Guide to Quality Improvement in Healthcare
123Pocket Guide to Quality Improvement in Healthcare
 
13-1 IntroductionThe Galleon Group was a privately owned hedge f
13-1 IntroductionThe Galleon Group was a privately owned hedge f13-1 IntroductionThe Galleon Group was a privately owned hedge f
13-1 IntroductionThe Galleon Group was a privately owned hedge f
 
13 Assessing Current Approaches to Childhood Immunizatio
13 Assessing Current Approaches to Childhood Immunizatio13 Assessing Current Approaches to Childhood Immunizatio
13 Assessing Current Approaches to Childhood Immunizatio
 
12Women Veterans Mental Healthcare
12Women Veterans Mental Healthcare12Women Veterans Mental Healthcare
12Women Veterans Mental Healthcare
 
1234 Oak StreetComment by Author Good letter format that f
1234 Oak StreetComment by Author Good letter format that f1234 Oak StreetComment by Author Good letter format that f
1234 Oak StreetComment by Author Good letter format that f
 
1252017PlayPositNameDate Francisco GonzalezL
1252017PlayPositNameDate Francisco GonzalezL1252017PlayPositNameDate Francisco GonzalezL
1252017PlayPositNameDate Francisco GonzalezL
 

Recently uploaded

Computed Fields and api Depends in the Odoo 17
Computed Fields and api Depends in the Odoo 17Computed Fields and api Depends in the Odoo 17
Computed Fields and api Depends in the Odoo 17Celine George
 
KSHARA STURA .pptx---KSHARA KARMA THERAPY (CAUSTIC THERAPY)————IMP.OF KSHARA ...
KSHARA STURA .pptx---KSHARA KARMA THERAPY (CAUSTIC THERAPY)————IMP.OF KSHARA ...KSHARA STURA .pptx---KSHARA KARMA THERAPY (CAUSTIC THERAPY)————IMP.OF KSHARA ...
KSHARA STURA .pptx---KSHARA KARMA THERAPY (CAUSTIC THERAPY)————IMP.OF KSHARA ...M56BOOKSTORE PRODUCT/SERVICE
 
“Oh GOSH! Reflecting on Hackteria's Collaborative Practices in a Global Do-It...
“Oh GOSH! Reflecting on Hackteria's Collaborative Practices in a Global Do-It...“Oh GOSH! Reflecting on Hackteria's Collaborative Practices in a Global Do-It...
“Oh GOSH! Reflecting on Hackteria's Collaborative Practices in a Global Do-It...Marc Dusseiller Dusjagr
 
Enzyme, Pharmaceutical Aids, Miscellaneous Last Part of Chapter no 5th.pdf
Enzyme, Pharmaceutical Aids, Miscellaneous Last Part of Chapter no 5th.pdfEnzyme, Pharmaceutical Aids, Miscellaneous Last Part of Chapter no 5th.pdf
Enzyme, Pharmaceutical Aids, Miscellaneous Last Part of Chapter no 5th.pdfSumit Tiwari
 
Earth Day Presentation wow hello nice great
Earth Day Presentation wow hello nice greatEarth Day Presentation wow hello nice great
Earth Day Presentation wow hello nice greatYousafMalik24
 
Employee wellbeing at the workplace.pptx
Employee wellbeing at the workplace.pptxEmployee wellbeing at the workplace.pptx
Employee wellbeing at the workplace.pptxNirmalaLoungPoorunde1
 
Introduction to AI in Higher Education_draft.pptx
Introduction to AI in Higher Education_draft.pptxIntroduction to AI in Higher Education_draft.pptx
Introduction to AI in Higher Education_draft.pptxpboyjonauth
 
Biting mechanism of poisonous snakes.pdf
Biting mechanism of poisonous snakes.pdfBiting mechanism of poisonous snakes.pdf
Biting mechanism of poisonous snakes.pdfadityarao40181
 
Software Engineering Methodologies (overview)
Software Engineering Methodologies (overview)Software Engineering Methodologies (overview)
Software Engineering Methodologies (overview)eniolaolutunde
 
Organic Name Reactions for the students and aspirants of Chemistry12th.pptx
Organic Name Reactions  for the students and aspirants of Chemistry12th.pptxOrganic Name Reactions  for the students and aspirants of Chemistry12th.pptx
Organic Name Reactions for the students and aspirants of Chemistry12th.pptxVS Mahajan Coaching Centre
 
History Class XII Ch. 3 Kinship, Caste and Class (1).pptx
History Class XII Ch. 3 Kinship, Caste and Class (1).pptxHistory Class XII Ch. 3 Kinship, Caste and Class (1).pptx
History Class XII Ch. 3 Kinship, Caste and Class (1).pptxsocialsciencegdgrohi
 
How to Configure Email Server in Odoo 17
How to Configure Email Server in Odoo 17How to Configure Email Server in Odoo 17
How to Configure Email Server in Odoo 17Celine George
 
Roles & Responsibilities in Pharmacovigilance
Roles & Responsibilities in PharmacovigilanceRoles & Responsibilities in Pharmacovigilance
Roles & Responsibilities in PharmacovigilanceSamikshaHamane
 
ECONOMIC CONTEXT - PAPER 1 Q3: NEWSPAPERS.pptx
ECONOMIC CONTEXT - PAPER 1 Q3: NEWSPAPERS.pptxECONOMIC CONTEXT - PAPER 1 Q3: NEWSPAPERS.pptx
ECONOMIC CONTEXT - PAPER 1 Q3: NEWSPAPERS.pptxiammrhaywood
 
POINT- BIOCHEMISTRY SEM 2 ENZYMES UNIT 5.pptx
POINT- BIOCHEMISTRY SEM 2 ENZYMES UNIT 5.pptxPOINT- BIOCHEMISTRY SEM 2 ENZYMES UNIT 5.pptx
POINT- BIOCHEMISTRY SEM 2 ENZYMES UNIT 5.pptxSayali Powar
 
Types of Journalistic Writing Grade 8.pptx
Types of Journalistic Writing Grade 8.pptxTypes of Journalistic Writing Grade 8.pptx
Types of Journalistic Writing Grade 8.pptxEyham Joco
 
18-04-UA_REPORT_MEDIALITERAСY_INDEX-DM_23-1-final-eng.pdf
18-04-UA_REPORT_MEDIALITERAСY_INDEX-DM_23-1-final-eng.pdf18-04-UA_REPORT_MEDIALITERAСY_INDEX-DM_23-1-final-eng.pdf
18-04-UA_REPORT_MEDIALITERAСY_INDEX-DM_23-1-final-eng.pdfssuser54595a
 

Recently uploaded (20)

Computed Fields and api Depends in the Odoo 17
Computed Fields and api Depends in the Odoo 17Computed Fields and api Depends in the Odoo 17
Computed Fields and api Depends in the Odoo 17
 
KSHARA STURA .pptx---KSHARA KARMA THERAPY (CAUSTIC THERAPY)————IMP.OF KSHARA ...
KSHARA STURA .pptx---KSHARA KARMA THERAPY (CAUSTIC THERAPY)————IMP.OF KSHARA ...KSHARA STURA .pptx---KSHARA KARMA THERAPY (CAUSTIC THERAPY)————IMP.OF KSHARA ...
KSHARA STURA .pptx---KSHARA KARMA THERAPY (CAUSTIC THERAPY)————IMP.OF KSHARA ...
 
“Oh GOSH! Reflecting on Hackteria's Collaborative Practices in a Global Do-It...
“Oh GOSH! Reflecting on Hackteria's Collaborative Practices in a Global Do-It...“Oh GOSH! Reflecting on Hackteria's Collaborative Practices in a Global Do-It...
“Oh GOSH! Reflecting on Hackteria's Collaborative Practices in a Global Do-It...
 
Enzyme, Pharmaceutical Aids, Miscellaneous Last Part of Chapter no 5th.pdf
Enzyme, Pharmaceutical Aids, Miscellaneous Last Part of Chapter no 5th.pdfEnzyme, Pharmaceutical Aids, Miscellaneous Last Part of Chapter no 5th.pdf
Enzyme, Pharmaceutical Aids, Miscellaneous Last Part of Chapter no 5th.pdf
 
Earth Day Presentation wow hello nice great
Earth Day Presentation wow hello nice greatEarth Day Presentation wow hello nice great
Earth Day Presentation wow hello nice great
 
Employee wellbeing at the workplace.pptx
Employee wellbeing at the workplace.pptxEmployee wellbeing at the workplace.pptx
Employee wellbeing at the workplace.pptx
 
TataKelola dan KamSiber Kecerdasan Buatan v022.pdf
TataKelola dan KamSiber Kecerdasan Buatan v022.pdfTataKelola dan KamSiber Kecerdasan Buatan v022.pdf
TataKelola dan KamSiber Kecerdasan Buatan v022.pdf
 
Introduction to AI in Higher Education_draft.pptx
Introduction to AI in Higher Education_draft.pptxIntroduction to AI in Higher Education_draft.pptx
Introduction to AI in Higher Education_draft.pptx
 
Biting mechanism of poisonous snakes.pdf
Biting mechanism of poisonous snakes.pdfBiting mechanism of poisonous snakes.pdf
Biting mechanism of poisonous snakes.pdf
 
Software Engineering Methodologies (overview)
Software Engineering Methodologies (overview)Software Engineering Methodologies (overview)
Software Engineering Methodologies (overview)
 
Organic Name Reactions for the students and aspirants of Chemistry12th.pptx
Organic Name Reactions  for the students and aspirants of Chemistry12th.pptxOrganic Name Reactions  for the students and aspirants of Chemistry12th.pptx
Organic Name Reactions for the students and aspirants of Chemistry12th.pptx
 
9953330565 Low Rate Call Girls In Rohini Delhi NCR
9953330565 Low Rate Call Girls In Rohini  Delhi NCR9953330565 Low Rate Call Girls In Rohini  Delhi NCR
9953330565 Low Rate Call Girls In Rohini Delhi NCR
 
History Class XII Ch. 3 Kinship, Caste and Class (1).pptx
History Class XII Ch. 3 Kinship, Caste and Class (1).pptxHistory Class XII Ch. 3 Kinship, Caste and Class (1).pptx
History Class XII Ch. 3 Kinship, Caste and Class (1).pptx
 
Model Call Girl in Tilak Nagar Delhi reach out to us at 🔝9953056974🔝
Model Call Girl in Tilak Nagar Delhi reach out to us at 🔝9953056974🔝Model Call Girl in Tilak Nagar Delhi reach out to us at 🔝9953056974🔝
Model Call Girl in Tilak Nagar Delhi reach out to us at 🔝9953056974🔝
 
How to Configure Email Server in Odoo 17
How to Configure Email Server in Odoo 17How to Configure Email Server in Odoo 17
How to Configure Email Server in Odoo 17
 
Roles & Responsibilities in Pharmacovigilance
Roles & Responsibilities in PharmacovigilanceRoles & Responsibilities in Pharmacovigilance
Roles & Responsibilities in Pharmacovigilance
 
ECONOMIC CONTEXT - PAPER 1 Q3: NEWSPAPERS.pptx
ECONOMIC CONTEXT - PAPER 1 Q3: NEWSPAPERS.pptxECONOMIC CONTEXT - PAPER 1 Q3: NEWSPAPERS.pptx
ECONOMIC CONTEXT - PAPER 1 Q3: NEWSPAPERS.pptx
 
POINT- BIOCHEMISTRY SEM 2 ENZYMES UNIT 5.pptx
POINT- BIOCHEMISTRY SEM 2 ENZYMES UNIT 5.pptxPOINT- BIOCHEMISTRY SEM 2 ENZYMES UNIT 5.pptx
POINT- BIOCHEMISTRY SEM 2 ENZYMES UNIT 5.pptx
 
Types of Journalistic Writing Grade 8.pptx
Types of Journalistic Writing Grade 8.pptxTypes of Journalistic Writing Grade 8.pptx
Types of Journalistic Writing Grade 8.pptx
 
18-04-UA_REPORT_MEDIALITERAСY_INDEX-DM_23-1-final-eng.pdf
18-04-UA_REPORT_MEDIALITERAСY_INDEX-DM_23-1-final-eng.pdf18-04-UA_REPORT_MEDIALITERAСY_INDEX-DM_23-1-final-eng.pdf
18-04-UA_REPORT_MEDIALITERAСY_INDEX-DM_23-1-final-eng.pdf
 

122820211Chapter Two Defining Crimes and Measurin

  • 1. 12/28/2021 1 Chapter Two: Defining Crimes and Measuring Criminal Behavior -Slides and data in this outline are from Adler, Mueller, and Laufer (2007, 2013, 2018 & 2022); Siegel (2015); and modified by Manning (2007, 2013, 2015, 2018 & 2022). Scared Straight Program – 1978 Rahway Max Prison -Politically motivated –fit the get tough on crime bill -Three year post experiment study shows evidence must be evidence based -Criminologists embrace a systematic empirical study of the nature and extent of crime. Example of successful criminology research based policy: -Domestic violence research between 1981-82 shows police counseling and temporary separation was not effective. -Now there are more mandatory arrest being made.
  • 2. 7 Basic Requirements for an Act to be a Crime Defense must prove failure of a basic requirement • 1. The act requirement – mind & Body • Conscious act not an unconscious act or reaction • Not a status or condition • 2. The legality requirement – prohibited by law • Thoughts without action – no crime • Choosing to not fill out sex registration forms – is a crime • Good Samaritan? • 3. The harm requirement • 4. The causation requirement • Behavior in question caused the harm – not a 3rd party • 5. The mens rea requirement (guilty mind) • 6. The concurrence requirement • Must be a criminal act with criminal intent (Ex: striker – rock –window) • Exceptions – felony murder • 7. The punishment requirement – its must already exist 12/28/2021 2 Criminal defense negates basic ingredients of crime. • Crime – must be known to the police
  • 3. • Not all crimes reported are cleared • DA will not always prosecute • Defense negation of crime elements examples: • Insanity defense; legality requirement lacking; duress, self- defense. • State tries cases on behalf of the state • Victims can file civil law suits for pain and suffering Typologies of Crime • The French created the following three categories accepted worldwide • Felonies - severe • Misdemeanors – minor • Violation - fines • As Criminologist we will also focus on the following • Violent crime • Crimes against property • White collar and corporate crime • Drug, alcohol and sex-related crime 12/28/2021 3
  • 4. Reasons for Measuring Crime • Researchers collect and analyze data to test theories about why people commit crime. • Researchers and criminal justice agencies need to enhance their knowledge of the characteristics of various types of offenses. • Criminal justice agencies depend on certain information to facilitate daily operations and anticipate future needs. The Research Process • Topic – research question • Theory: is a set of principles that explain how 2 or more phenomena are related • May choose to use a hypothesis or not. • Methodology (qualitative vs. quantitative) • Will you use secondary data or primary data • Analysis • What did you do, findings, discussions and conclusions 12/28/2021 4
  • 5. Exploring and defining the Thesis Process • Abstract • Introduction • Methodology – Analysis of secondary data • Theory • Methodology – Exploration of primary data • Findings • Discussion and Conclusions • References Methodologies used to Collect Primary Data on Crime • 1. Survey Research • And interviews • 2. Experiments • 3. Observation • 4. Participant Observation • 5. Case Studies 12/28/2021 5
  • 6. Surveys and interviews explored • The systematic collection of respondents’ answers to questions asked in questionnaires or interviews. • Population • Sample • Random Sample Experiments • An investigator introduces a change into a process and makes measurements or observations in order to evaluate the effects of the change. • Variables: • Independent Variable A causes Dependent Variable B to Change • Control Group • Pretest and post test 12/28/2021 6 Participant and Non-Participant Observation
  • 7. • In participant observation the researcher may join and participate in the activities of the group being studied. • In observational research the researcher observes the group being studies but is not a participant in the activities. • This process may be used to study criminals, prisoners, prosecutors, or police officers. Case Studies • A case study is an analysis of all pertinent aspects of one unit of study, such as an individual, an institution, a group or a community. • Sources of information may be life histories, biographies, diaries, journals, letters, and other records. • Edwin Sutherlands “The Professional Thief” 12/28/2021 7 Ethics and Research in Criminology researcher responsibilities studying “vulnerable populations” • Should the results of interviews be published? • If the research does not disclose names could the participant be
  • 8. obstructing justice? • Is there confidentiality for a criminal suspect? • Does a researcher have to turn over his/her files if requested by the police or court? • Should criminologists be immune from prosecution? • Is it possible to develop a technique that can ensure against identification of the subjects in a file? • Informed consent, avoid invasion of privacy • Do no harm: mental, physical or financial harms Major Sources of Crime Information • Uniform Crime Report (UCR) - Part I and Part II offenses • Published by the Federal Bureau of Investigation • J. Edgar Hoover given permission in 1930 (FBI) • Part II offenses • 21 crimes (all non part I except traffic violations) • Ex: fraud, embezzlement, weapons, vandalism, simple assaults, sex crimes, drugs, gambling, disorderly conduct and vagrancy. • National Crime Victimization Survey • Self-Report Studies
  • 9. 12/28/2021 8 FBI Part I Index Offenses • Strengths • Most consistent source of homicides and arrests • Weakness • Many crimes not reported, there are reporting errors, most drug crimes omitted, white collar crimes omitted. • Does not differentiate between attempted and completed. • Cleared only means an arrest was made. Crimes against the person -Murder -Rape -Assault -Robbery Crimes against property -Burglary -Larceny -Motor Vehicle Theft -Arson Victimization Surveys • National Crime Victimization Survey (NCVS) • Measure the extent of crime by interviewing individuals about their experiences as victims. • Published by the Bureau of Justice Statistics
  • 10. • 90,000 households, 160,000 people • Cycle reports every three years. • Covers time, place, offenders, weapons etc. • Strengths: • includes crimes not reported, careful sampling of gen. pop. • Weakness: relies on victims memory and honesty (telescoping). • One index crime not included- which one? 12/28/2021 9 Self-Report Surveys • A self-report study ask people to report their own criminal acts in a confidential interview or, more commonly, on an anonymous questionnaire. • These reports have demonstrated very high rates of l aw- violating behavior by seemingly law-abiding people. • Most violate some laws. • Strengths: • includes non reported crimes, substance abuse and personal information. • Weakness:
  • 11. • focus on petty crimes • Honesty of self-reporting participants. Crime Trends • Crimes rose slowly between 1930-60. • Rose fast from 1960-1980 and then dropped till 1984. • Peeked: rose until 1991. • Crimes have been decreasing since 1991. • Between 2014 and 2018 there was a 4.7% increase in violent crimes with a 14.6% decrease in property crimes (Adler, Mueller, & Laufer, 2022, p. 44). • More crime happens in the Southern states. • More crime in urban areas • More victimization within five miles of home and in your own home • 50% violent crimes happen between 6 a.m. – 6 p.m. • 67% of sexual assaults, household larcenies, and 75% of motor vehicle theft happens at night. • While most juvenile crimes occur after school 3 p.m. – 7 p.m. 12/28/2021 10 Age and Crime • Peek Crimes years 16-24 • Siegel (2015) says 16 for property crime and
  • 12. • 18 for violent crime • Half of all arrest are of individual under age 25 • Juveniles account for 15% of all index crimes in 2006 at 8% of pop. • 25% of larceny theft and 50% of all arson arrests. • Arrest rates decline after age 30 Aging Out Vs. Life Course Perspectives • Aging out phenomenon • Too old for crime – employment and relationships. • Life Course: environmental factors • Class, poverty, unemployment, peers and opportunity • Chronic Offenders – a study of Philadelphia youth born in 1945 • 1972 publication on the males (9,945) • 35% contact with police by age 18, 46% of the offenders were one time offenders, 18% five or more which was 6% of the total group studied know as the Chronic 6%. • The females (14,000 • 14% police contact by age 18, of those 60% one time offenders, 33% repeat and 7% of total group were chronic offenders • Less violent crimes.
  • 13. 12/28/2021 11 Sex and Crime • Males commit more crimes than females at all ages • Arrest ratio: 3:1 however, the gap is closing • 1960s females accounted for only 11% of total arrests. • 2013 textbook stated 23% and now its 35% (Adler, Mueller & Laufer, 2022). • Female crimes are rising faster then the rate of boys. • What Three offences do women commit more than men? • Prostitution, shoplifting, and welfare fraud. • Explanation: as women's social, economic and political power increases so has their criminal activity (movies: wonder women and star war Jedi). • While more poor and more patriarchal families tend to restrict girls roles. Race and Crime • Blacks constitute 12.1% of USA pop. Yet 27% of all arrest for index crimes (Adler, Mueller, & Laufer, 2022). • 50% of black urban males are arrested for an index crime once in their
  • 14. lifetime compared to 14% of white males. • 18% of blacks serve some time in prison but only 3% of white males. • Blacks have a higher risk of death do to violence. • Debating the explanations: • Does it represent a bias CJ system? Or do Blacks commit more crimes? • While debates over class and crime remains controversial there is no debate over the class of those in prison? Most made less then $5,600 before prison. • Lower class commit more serious crimes (burglary, robbery, assaults and sexual assaults). Disruptive Innovation . . . in Reverse: Adding a Geographical Dimension to Disruptive Innovation Theory Simone Corsi and Alberto Di Minin Based on a literature review on disruptive innovation and innovation from emerging econo- mies, we offer an interpretation of a subset of reverse innovation within the disruptive innovation theory. We argue that the combination of these two theories provides a useful framework to look at emerging economies as sources of new products and technological solutions. Finally, we provide a new categorization of
  • 15. disruptive innovation considering a geographical dimension and future research directions. Introduction In a fast-changing world, where emergingeconomies are constantly increasing their importance in the global economy and where innovation assumes an international dimen- sion, an increasing number of scholars have looked at the phenomenon of innovation in emerging economies. Several authors are investigating in what way these countries are not only recipients (Vernon, 1966) but also sources of innovation (Hart & Christensen, 2002; Immelt, Govindarajan & Trimble, 2009; Kenney, Massini & Murtha, 2009; Govindarajan & Trimble, 2012). Scholars refer to this trend in different ways, depending on the aspect they focus on, such as ‘disruptive innovation from emerging econo- mies’ (Hart & Christensen, 2002), ‘innovation at the bottom of the pyramid’ (Prahalad, 2004), ‘cost-innovation’ (Zeng & Williamson, 2007) or ‘reverse innovation’ (Immelt, Govindarajan & Trimble, 2009). However, the managerial lit- erature is still lacking both a clear and solid theoretical position and a strong theoretical framework within which a new innovation trend from emerging economies can be read and interpreted (Govindarajan & Ramamurti, 2011). Hence, the aim of this paper is firstly to critically review the literature concerning innovation from emerging economies, and sec- ondly to contribute a rationalization of the
  • 16. related concepts, attempting a reinterpretation of the concept of ‘reverse innovation’ (Immelt, Govindarajan & Trimble, 2009; Govindarajan & Trimble, 2012), defined as a type of ‘disrup- tive innovation’ (Christensen, 1997). Building on our review of the existing work (see Appendix A and Table 1), we suggest that the combination of these two frameworks pro- vides a useful scheme to look at emerging economies as sources of new products and technological solutions. In the last ten years, scholars have started to look at companies that serve those markets in a different way. Glocalization – adapting to emerging markets products developed for advanced ones – is in fact assumed to be par- tially ‘blind’ or ineffective for the purpose of serving emerging market needs, given its ability to reach only the wealthier part of the population. The new challenge of the twenty- first century has been identified in the profit- able development and sale of new products for the mass markets of less affluent populations of emerging economies that are currently not, or only partially, served by multinational cor- porations (MNCs). The innovation manage- ment literature has produced a limited number of studies (Hart & Christensen, 2002; Prahalad, 2004; Immelt, Govindarajan & Trimble, 2009; Hang, Chen & Subramanian, 2010; Govindarajan & Trimble, 2012), largely based on anecdotal evidence, trying to identify new ways of pursuing innovation in emerging
  • 17. economies. Most of these studies build their 76 CREATIVITY AND INNOVATION MANAGEMENT Volume 23 Number 1 2014 10.1111/caim.12043 © 2013 John Wiley & Sons Ltd argument, more or less implicitly, on the well- known ‘disruptive innovation’ paradigm as defined by Christensen (1997) and Christensen and Raynor (2003), further derived as disrup- tive innovation in emerging economies in Prahalad’s seminal work on innovation for the ‘bottom of the pyramid’ (BOP) (Prahalad, 2004). Given the specificity of the context for and in which these innovations need to be devel- Table 1. Main Innovation Concepts Related to Emerging Economies (Literature and Examples) Concept Literature Examples Disruptive Innovation Acee (2001); Anthony et al. (2006); Bower & Christensen (1995); Cefis & Marsili (2006); Charitou & Markides (2003); Christensen (1997, 2006); Christensen & Overdorf
  • 18. (2000); Christensen & Raynor (2003); Christensen et al. (2000, 2006); Chesbrough (2002); Corso & Pellegrini (2007); Danneels (2004); Gilbert (2003); Gilbert & Bower (2002); Glazer (2007); Govindarajan (2012); Govindarajan & Kopalle (2006a, 2006b); Govindarajan et al. (2011); Henderson (2006); Johnson et al. (2008); Johnson (2012); Kanter (2010); Kassicieh et al. (2002); Mangelsdorf (2009); Markides (2006); O’Reilly & Tushman (2004); Rafii & Kampas (2002); Sandström, Magnusson & Jörnmark (2009); Schmidt & Druehl (2008); Simanis & Hart (2009); Suzuki & Kodama (2004); Utterback & Acee (2005); Yu & Hang (2010, 2011) Hard disk drive; digital photography; mobile phone Disruptive Innovation from Emerging Economies Hang et al. (2010); London & Hart (2004); Markides (2012); Ray & Ray (2011); Schanz et al. (2011) Galanz’s microwave; Suzlon’s windmills; Haier’s washing machine Innovation for
  • 19. the Bottom of the Pyramid Akula (2008); Anderson et al. (2010); Ansari et al. (2012); Garrette & Karnani (2010); Gino & Staats (2012); Hart & Christensen (2002); Karamchandani et al. (2011); Karnani (2007); Olsen & Boxembaum (2009); Prahalad (2004, 2012); Prahalad & Hammond (2002); Prahalad & Hart (2002); Rangan et al. (2011); Simanis (2012); Wood & Hamel (2002) Aravind Eye Care’s hospitals; ICICI Bank’s microcredit; Casas Bahia’s retailers Cost Innovation Williamson (2010); Williamson & Zeng (2004, 2009); Zeng & Williamson (2007) China International Marine Containers Group’s shipping service; Dawning’s high performance computers Reverse Innovation Govindarajan and Trimble (2012); Immelt, Govindarajan & Trimble (2009) GE Healthcare’s ECG machine; P&G’s honey-based cold
  • 20. remedy; P&G’s feminine hygiene product; Tata Nano DISRUPTIVE INNOVATION . . . IN REVERSE 77 Volume 23 Number 1 2014 © 2013 John Wiley & Sons Ltd oped, domestic companies seem to be best placed to pursue them. By virtue of their embeddedness, local market knowledge and low cost approach, domestic companies develop new product solutions for emerging markets that challenge the activities of foreign MNCs. This phenomenon has mostly been referred to as ‘cost innovation’ (Zeng & Williamson, 2007). Indeed, growing attention has been paid to companies from emerging economies and how in going global they threaten western MNCs in the home markets that they have dominated for decades. Responding to this threat is a new challenge for incumbent MNCs and, in our opinion, ‘dis- ruptive innovation’ is a useful way to describe the new trend that has recently been defined as ‘reverse innovation’ (Immelt, Govindarajan & Trimble, 2009). According to Immelt, Govindarajan and Trimble (2009) and Govindarajan and Trimble (2012), since most current and future global economic growth is likely to take place in emerging economies, innovation specifically aimed at responding to these markets is crucial. Indeed, new products
  • 21. developed entirely in emerging markets for emerging markets are likely to disrupt devel- oped markets and open new business oppor- tunities, as shown, for example, by Zeng and Williamson (2007). This phenomenon thus configures a process of innovation that no longer sees developed economies as the locus where new products are conceived, designed and commercialized, but instead takes on the role of the last recipient of innovations devel- oped in and for emerging economies. This paper builds on the disruptive innova- tion literature and contrasts its analysis with the concept of reverse innovation. We believe we bring two theoretical contributions: 1. Adding a geographical dimension to disruptive innovation. The original specification of disruptive innovation is a theory that seeks to explain dynamics within established markets. However, a geographical dimen- sion needs to be considered to make disrup- tive innovation useful for interpreting situations where the disruptors originate from emerging markets. 2. A new look at disruptive and reverse innovation side by side. Consistent with Govindarajan and Trimble (2012), we emphasize that the concepts of disruptive and reverse innova- tion have an overlapping, though not a one- to-one, relationship. By looking at these two theories side by side, we are able to better clarify similarities and differences. We dis- tance ourselves from the claim that disrup-
  • 22. tive innovation in reverse stems only from an income gap. On the contrary, disruptive in reverse rests not only on cost advantage in the market segment but also on new characteristics and features of the disrup- tive product originated and tested in a developing country and appreciated in advanced countries. This paper is organized as follows. In the next section, we lay the foundations of our analysis by reviewing disruptive innovation theory. This will be used as our framework to interpret the other sections that take into account disruptive innovation as considered in the different streams of literature related to innovation in emerging economies. The third section explores the dynamics of innovation at the Bottom of the Pyramid (BOP), while the fourth section investigates the conceptuali- zation of disruptive innovation from emerging economies. The concept of reverse innovation is introduced in the fifth section and inter- preted within the Disruptive Innovation framework in the sixth section. The seventh section provides a new categorization of Dis- ruptive Innovation, considering a geographi- cal dimension. Finally, conclusions and future research directions are presented together with selected research propositions. Disruptive Innovation Introduced in 1995 by Bower and Christensen, the concept of disruptive innovation was
  • 23. refined by Christensen in 1997 with his ‘Inn- ovator’s Dilemma’, asking why great compa- nies pursuing innovation in mainstream markets suffer from market myopia and are overtaken by entrant firms introducing prod- ucts based on new, disruptive technologies. To explain this phenomenon, Christensen distinguishes between sustaining and disrup- tive technologies. The former are technologies that respond to an improvement, radical or incremental, of ‘established products, along the dimensions of performance that main- stream customers in major markets have his- torically valued’ (Christensen, 1997, p. xv). Disruptive technologies, on the other hand, are innovations for existing products but on attributes that differ from those that are mainly valued by mainstream customers. These inno- vations, which initially underperform with respect to the main attributes of sustaining technologies, become disruptive when they reach the same performance as the sustaining innovations on the attributes valued by main- stream customers. At this point, they displace existing technologies and cause, in most cases, the failure of incumbent firms. Christensen describes as an example the evolution of the 78 CREATIVITY AND INNOVATION MANAGEMENT Volume 23 Number 1 2014 © 2013 John Wiley & Sons Ltd
  • 24. hard disk drive industry between 1976 and 1992. In this market, mainstream customers constantly required improvements in two attributes, total capacity and recording density. The industry and incumbent firms were led by this trend until an emerging segment asked for improvements on different attributes, in par- ticular, the size of drivers. At the beginning, this segment remained marginal and was mainly covered by small entrant firms that could afford to do so by virtue of their rela- tively limited cost structure, but while the products offered gained improved perfor- mance, including the mainstream segment attributes, the market based on sustaining technologies was progressively displaced, causing the failure of incumbents. In earlier works, Christensen (Bower & Christensen, 1995; Christensen, 1997) refers to disruptive technology only as an ‘innovation that results in worse product performance in mainstream markets’. It is also described as a ‘typically cheaper, simpler, smaller and fre- quently more convenient to use’ version of an existing product. In an updated version of the concept, Christensen and Raynor (2003) distinguish between ‘low-end disruptions’ and ‘(new- market) high-end disruptions’. The former are those offering lower performance at a cheaper price but no other performance improve- ments, while the latter are described as prod- ucts and services that offer better performance on attributes that differ from those valued by
  • 25. mainstream customers (e.g., the mobile phone, initially low performing in reception, which disrupted the market for home phones). Christensen also asserts that disruptive technologies should be framed as a marke- ting, and not a technological, challenge (Christensen, 2006; Glazer, 2007). Firms suc- ceeding in disruptive innovations have a strong attitude in interpreting and addressing needs expressed by a market niche or a new market segment. Thus, the challenge that incumbent firms should overcome in develop- ing and responding to disruptive innovatio ns relates to the development of capabilities to forecast market trends and attitudes as well as ‘riding’ new technological trajectories (Rafii & Kampas, 2002; Charitou & Markides, 2003; Suzuki & Kodama, 2004; Corso & Pellegrini, 2007). Disruptive innovation has been used from the very beginning to discuss innovation dynamics taking place with the entry of new companies in established and developed markets (Chesbrough, 2002). One of the most convincing responses provided by research- ers, albeit widely discussed and doubted (Danneels, 2004), is that these companies should promote the creation of spin-off enter- prises in order to better serve and interpret emerging markets (O’Reilly & Tushman, 2004; Kanter, 2010; Johnson, 2012). The creation of a separate organization of a smaller dimension with large autonomy allows the problem of
  • 26. resource allocation that is too mainstream cus- tomer oriented to be overcome. Matching the initially small market size to the size of the investment potentially enables the new company to be profitable (Kassicieh et al., 2002; Anthony, Eyring & Gibson, 2006; Cefis & Marsili, 2006; Sandström, Magnusson & Jörnmark, 2009). Since its coinage, the concept of disruptive innovation has been widely discussed from different perspectives (Christensen, Bohmer & Kenagy, 2000; Christensen, Johnson & Rigby, 2002; Gilbert & Bower, 2002; Gilbert, 2003; Danneels, 2004; Christensen et al., 2006; Henderson, 2006; Johnson, Christensen & Kagermann, 2008; Schmidt & Druehl, 2008; Yu & Hang, 2010, 2011). In particular, Govindarajan and Kopalle (2006a, 2006b) make a clear distinction between low-end and high-end disruptions based on the level of radicalness of disruptive innovations (techno- logically more radical in high-end disruptions, technologically less radical in low-end disrup- tions). The authors also make a clear distinc- tion between innovations that are radical and disruptive and merely radical, stating that radicalness is a technology-based concept while disruptiveness is a market-based concept. Analogously, Markides (2006) draws a clear distinction between different kinds of disruptive innovations: technological, business model and new-to-the-world product innova- tions. From this distinction and from the work of Utterback (2004), Acee (2001) and Utterback and Acee (2005), who recognized the impor-
  • 27. tance of disruptive technologies not in the fact that they displace existing products but in their ability to enlarge existing markets and provide new functionalities, Govindarajan and Kopalle add rigour to an expanded view of disruptive innovation, including both high- end and low-end disruptions and define the concept as follow (2006a, p. 190): A disruptive innovation introduces a differ- ent set of features, performance and price attributes relative to the existing product, an unattractive combination for mainstream customers at the time of product introduc- tion because of inferior performance on the attributes these customers value and/or a high price – although a different customer segment may value the new attributes. Sub- sequent developments over time, however, raise the new product’s attributes to a level DISRUPTIVE INNOVATION . . . IN REVERSE 79 Volume 23 Number 1 2014 © 2013 John Wiley & Sons Ltd sufficient to satisfy mainstream customers, thus attracting more of the mainstream market. In the examples of disruptive technologies provided by Christensen (1997) and Christensen and Raynor (2003), the new market segment that adopts the disruptive
  • 28. solution belongs to the same market where incumbent companies operate. The emergence of new technologies triggers interest within the mainstream segment where these incum- bents operate, hence rendering access to the disruptive offering (initially not desired) also possible to mainstream customers (Govindarajan, Kopalle & Danneels, 2011). In conclusion, we can argue that disruptive innovation is a theory that seeks to explain changes and new entries into established markets. The result of disruptive innovation is visible when mainstream customers switch to the new disruptive product that is gaining market share on established markets. What if the new disruptive solution has been brought to maturity and has triggered interest in markets that are geographically distant and disconnected from established markets? Disruptive innovation theory was not developed, and is as yet too unrefined, to explain this phenomenon. Innovation at the Bottom of the Pyramid (BOP) While the disruptive innovation paradigm explores the dynamics originating within the hub of an industry, a new approach was devel- oped to understand what was taking place in emerging economies and their markets (Karnani, 2007; Akula, 2008; Gino & Staats, 2012). This orientation brought scholars to thinking of emerging economies as focal
  • 29. markets to which companies should pay increasing attention and develop a new R&D orientation (Prahalad & Hart, 2002). Traditionally, MNCs delocalized their R&D- oriented foreign direct investment (FDI) in emerging economies for two main reasons (Gassmann & Han, 2004; Von Zedtwitz, 2004): • access to local markets, • access to high-skilled research personnel at a lower cost. Following these two drivers, most R&D carried out by foreign MNCs in emerging countries consisted in the adaptation of global products to the specific needs of the local market. R&D, crucial for the development of new products, has traditionally been undis- closed by headquarters (Patel & Pavitt, 1991; Di Minin & Bianchi, 2011), and this is particularly true of R&D internationalization in emerging economies. The new perspective in the early 2000s was that emerging market potential was not exploited with the previous approach and that a new type of innovation management had to be developed. Companies noted that respond- ing to local market needs with a simple local adaptation of global products developed in their (mainly) western headquarters (glocali- zation) was ineffective in exploiting the entire potential of these growing markets (London &
  • 30. Hart, 2004; Rangan, Chu & Petkoski, 2011). Prahalad and Hart (2002), and later on Prahalad (2004), introduced the new approach to emerging economies as a source of signifi- cant profit generation through the develop- ment and commercialization of ad hoc products and services for the markets of the poor (Garrette & Karnani, 2010; Simanis, 2012). Prahalad’s approach is expressed in the title of his 2004 book The Fortune at the Bottom of the Pyramid: Eradicating Poverty through Profits. The author identifies a large opportunity both for local and MNCs operating in emerging econo- mies and provides examples such as ICICI Bank, which provides Indian rural populations with bank credit for small projects (which in turn become profitable and make them able to return the loan with low interest), or Voxiva, which developed a text message-based plat- form for favouring communication between urban and health centres in Peru. Both projects, based on low cost and pricing strategies, faced an experimental stage for the purpose of vali- dating their economic feasibility and soon moved forward, replicating their model in other emerging countries and contexts. According to Prahalad’s perspective, MNCs serving only the top of the pyramid (the wealthier part of the population) in emerging economies suffer from business myopia in a way that closely recalls the marketing chal- lenge that Christensen’s incumbent firms faced in developing disruptive innovation for new or emerging market niches.
  • 31. What is of great interest to us is that, although there is no direct and explicit link between these theories, the BOP concept shares some similarities with the disruptive innovation theory (Hart & Christensen, 2002; Prahalad & Hammond, 2002; Prahalad, 2012). It suggests developing products and services for a market segment requesting different attributes than those of mainstream customers (Wood & Hamel 2002; Seelos & Mair, 2007; Anderson, Markides & Kupp, 2010) and, in particular, access to the same technology at a much lower price. In reality, it addresses a 80 CREATIVITY AND INNOVATION MANAGEMENT Volume 23 Number 1 2014 © 2013 John Wiley & Sons Ltd market that does not yet exist, seemingly con- figuring what Govindarajan and Kopalle (2006a, 2006b) identify as disruptive innova- tion that creates a new market. In our opinion, innovation at the BOP cannot be easily, or entirely, assimilated with disruptive innova- tion theory. We will explain why in the next section, explicitly linking the BOP to the dis- ruptive innovation paradigm. Disruptive Innovations from Emerging Economies Parallel to the work on ‘Serving the Bottom of
  • 32. the Pyramid’, a further wave of exploration was initiated by scholars linking the disruptive innovation theory and Prahalad’s non-served markets of the poorest in emerging economies (Hart & Christensen, 2002; London & Hart, 2004). The argument of scholars applying disrup- tive innovation to explain the success of new products originating from emerging econo- mies is as follows: foreign MNCs develop products for emerging markets and later use them to penetrate the low-end segment of developed markets in the US and Europe, and domestic firms leverage on their cost structure and knowledge of the domestic context to serve local, and later developed, markets (Ray & Ray, 2011; Schanz et al., 2011; Markides, 2012). To the best of our knowledge, Hart and Christensen (2002) for the first time introduced the link between disruptive innovation theory and emerging economies. Their argument is clearly in line with Prahalad’s work referring to ‘innovation from the base of the pyramid’. The authors propose examples of Asian com- panies that succeeded in introducing disrup- tive innovations in low-income countries, enabling poor people to afford certain types of technological products and generating profits for themselves. Recently, Hang, Chen and Subramanian (2010) demonstrated four cases of Asian com- panies that, starting from their low-income
  • 33. markets (China and India), developed disrup- tive products. Galanz and Haier, for example, developed ad hoc products for penetrating the Chinese domestic market and responding to specific local needs (a microwave for Galanz and a washing machine for Haier). Once they succeeded in China, they were able to export their product to developed countries serving a market segment that was ignored by incum- bents due to its size, a market segment that was eager for low-cost products with strong energy and room-saving attributes and that did not care about traditional attributes for those items such as capacity. After a few years of internal and external R&D investment, both companies were able to penetrate also the high-end of advanced economies’ markets, disrupting local incumbents. The success pursued in these markets brought them per- formance improvements on attributes that had at first been neglected and valued by main- stream customers in developed economies. This pushed them to invest globally and to steadily grow in developed economies. We believe that in both works cited above, the disruptive innovation concept is used in a way that differs from the traditional applica- tion of the concept within established markets in developed economies. The traditionally defined disruptive innovation paradigm (Bower & Christensen, 1995; Christensen, 1997) claims that new products (or services) are considered disruptive when they respond to an ignored and new market segment that is
  • 34. usually small, unprofitable for incumbents and has differentiated needs in terms of product attributes. Could we say that the idea of inno- vation originating in emerging markets pre- sented by Hart and Christensen (2002) is indeed a disruptive innovation? We think this is true only in part, and that three limitations need to be considered in relation to the char- acteristics of disruptiveness mentioned above. In particular, we need to consider (1) the categorization of mainstream and non- mainstream customers, (2) market size, and (3) disruptive innovators (see Table 2): 1. Companies operating in emerging econo- mies have traditionally served those markets adopting a glocalization approach to market segmentation, thus serving cus- tomers that correspond and share similar characteristics to those segments served back in their country of origin or in devel- oped markets. These are their mainstream customers, who might represent the great majority at home but in emerging econo- mies represent only the top of the pyramid. Adopting a marketing perspective instead, as the disruptive challenge requires us to (Christensen, 1997; Danneels, 2004), main- stream customers in emerging markets should be defined as the large part of the population (be it individuals or companies) that cannot afford expensive state-of-the-art technology and that are partly served by local companies that can interpret their needs and respond to them thanks to their cost structure.
  • 35. 2. One of the main challenges that incumbent firms face when developing or responding to disruptive innovations in their markets is that the size of the emerging market with DISRUPTIVE INNOVATION . . . IN REVERSE 81 Volume 23 Number 1 2014 © 2013 John Wiley & Sons Ltd different requirements is too small to cover the development costs of new products (Christensen, 1997; Christensen & Raynor, 2003). Indeed, the size of the market does not match the size of the company and its related cost structure as it does in the case of small entrants or spin-off companies. This is not true in emerging economies, where the market served by innovations, as in the cases presented in Hart and Christensen (2002) and Hang, Chen and Subramanian (2010), is much bigger than that served by glocal products, so that the market size is potentially huge, assuming that access to these market segments is feasible. 3. Disruptive innovations in developed econo- mies generally come from a small entrant firm (e.g., a start-up company) that is gen- erated by either a new entrepreneurial activity or a spin-off company from an incumbent firm (Bower & Christensen,
  • 36. 1995; Christensen, 1997; Walsh, Kirchhoff & Newbert, 2002; Christensen & Raynor, 2003). The generation of disruptive innova- tions in emerging economies could be developed by domestic companies that naturally have a cost structure and a market orientation that fits the local environment and by subsidiaries of MNCs that have evolved and gained enough autonomy to develop new products. The case of compa- nies from emerging markets is well described by Zeng and Williamson (2007) who report on how innovations developed by Chinese companies are disrupting global markets by primarily leveraging on new, low cost based, business models. The inno- vative approach of these companies is defined by the authors as ‘cost innovation’. Reverse Innovation In the previous sections, we showed how dis- ruptive innovation theory does not adequately fit the description of innovations developed for emerging economies and afterwards ‘exported’ back to developed economies. ‘Reverse innovation’ (Govindarajan, 2009; Immelt, Govindarajan & Trimble, 2009; Govindarajan & Trimble, 2012) is a more suit- able framework that helps us understand this trend. This new line of research emphasizes the role of emerging economies as the new laboratory in the global economy and argues that innovation is less likely to come from, and is adopted in, developed countries first, but is conceived and adopted in emerging econo-
  • 37. mies first to then be introduced to developed markets. It is then ‘exported’ to the developed economies. These dynamics reverse the inno- vation process as intended in the prior litera- ture and managerial practice. The reasons that support such an inverted process lie in the market growth of the developing countries that are supporting and leading the global economy. In their 2009 article ‘How GE is Disrupting Itself’, Immelt, Govindarajan and Trimble show how GE is benefiting from its presence in the markets of emerging economies, specifi- cally China and India, to develop break- through innovations that are introduced and successfully commercialized first in develop- ing countries and later, when performance improvements are acceptable, in developed countries. They provide clear examples for GE Healthcare developing and perfecting prod- ucts in both China (Immelt, Govindarajan & Trimble, 2009) and India (Govindarajan & Trimble, 2012) before selling them in those markets first and in advanced ones later on, disrupting existing products in some markets as a result of performance improvements on the attributes most valued by mainstream customers. The authors stress the importance of local growth teams (LGTs) as new units, independ- ent from their MNC headquarters (HQ), built from scratch in emerging economies. They are responsible for the complete development and
  • 38. commercialization of products leveraging HQ technology but developing completely new offerings that match the market they operate in. While GE Healthcare is a well-known example, there are other cases that present similar innovation paths. Esaote, an Italian medium-sized company that designs and manufactures medical diagnostic systems, is currently sourcing product ideas for the global market from its R&D laboratory located in Shenzhen (Corsi & Di Minin, 2012). These cases explain how in order to compete in emerging economies, foreign MNCs have to rely on LGTs in order to develop innovations that fit local needs and overcome local constraints. At the same time, they do not neglect the glocalization paradigm in line with which MNCs have to continue to operate to serve high-end markets and build part of the technological knowledge that is essential for the activities of LGTs in emerging economies. Overlapping Areas between Disruptive and Reverse Innovation Given the above considerations, the disruptive innovation theory can provide a useful tool for interpreting the phenomenon of innovation 82 CREATIVITY AND INNOVATION MANAGEMENT Volume 23 Number 1 2014 © 2013 John Wiley & Sons Ltd
  • 39. from emerging economies. As we showed in the above sections, scholars have already iden- tified this opportunity, but we think it needs to be refined and integrated with reverse innova- tion to effectively frame a reversed cycle of innovation. The characteristics that Immelt, Govindarajan and Trimble (2009) and Govindarajan and Trimble (2012) list and illus- trate to describe reverse innovation partly match those described in the previous sections of this paper recalling disruptive innova- tion theory as illustrated by Bower and Christensen (1995), Christensen (1997), Acee (2001), Christensen and Raynor (2003), Utterback and Acee (2005) and Govindarajan and Kopalle (2006a, 2006b). In particular, under specific circumstances reverse innova- tion shares great similarities with the idea of disruptive innovation from emerging econo- mies as illustrated by Hart and Christensen (2002), Zeng and Williamson (2007) and Hang, Chen and Subramanian (2010). Govindarajan and Trimble (2009) responded to this parallelism themselves following the requests of some readers of their paper who asked for clarification between disruptive innovation and reverse innovation. In one of Govindarajan’s blog posts (30 September 20091), they list a set of conditions that reverse innovation can originate from, stating that the one concerning a lower price offer is the only one configuring it also as a disruptive innova- tion. The same issue is addressed by
  • 40. Govindarajan and Trimble (2012). They thus consider disruptive innovation only from a price/performance point of view, and not as a market widener or as a provider of new functionalities, implicitly stating that disrup- tive innovation can only have a lower price. We do not believe this is completely true. Referring back to Govindarajan’s works on disruptive innovation, we note that Govindarajan and Kopalle (2006b) define dis- ruptive innovation as ‘a powerful means for broadening and developing new markets and providing new functionality, which, in turn, disrupt existing market linkages’. Therefore, the focus now lies in the alterna- tive attributes that are offered by the innova- tion in relation to an existing product. These new products are able to penetrate the market starting from early adopters and improve per- formance in the ‘mainstream’ thanks to the experience accumulated in serving the new segment. In line with Christensen and Raynor (2003) and Utterback and Acee (2005), Govindarajan and Kopalle (2006a) define dis- ruptive innovation in the way presented in the second section of this paper and include both new, low-end and high-end attributes to exist- ing products that initially are tempting only to new customers (thus not necessarily price- focused) or the most price-sensitive main- stream customers, but in developing over time they also gain the attention of mainstream cus- tomers and the market.
  • 41. In summary, Govindarajan and Trimble (2012) state that reverse innovation has five drivers, named ‘gaps’ (performance, infra- structure, sustainability, regulatory, prefer- ences), but the examples they provide in their work (Immelt, Govindarajan & Trimble, 2009; Govindarajan & Ramamurti, 2011; Govindarajan & Trimble, 2012) stress funda- mentally the income (or performance) gap (Logitech Mouse in China, P&G feminine hygiene product in Mexico, Deere Tractor in India, Harman infotainment system in India and China), and indirectly lead us to under- stand that reverse innovation takes the direc- tion of a potential disruptive effect only when an equivalent income gap can be found isolat- ing a segment of the market in an advanced economy. While we acknowledge that indeed the income gap is a key driver, the emphasis of Christensen’s low-end disruptive innovation is on new markets being created, and new value networks displacing the old ones. Such dyna- mics in reverse-disruptive innovation happen not only when a company from emerging coun- tries enters advanced ones to serve the needs of a less affluent market segment, but indeed dis- ruption occurs when the technological evolu- tion and market experience lead this offering to go from the niche to the main market. In these situations of reverse-disruptive innovations, we indeed identify the following common elements between reverse innovation and dis- ruptive innovation: the same risks of cannibalizations for companies that have previ- ously invested in the same industries for main-
  • 42. stream customers (Govindarajan & Kopalle, 2006a, 2006b; Immelt, Govindarajan & Trimble, 2009), which is also a tool for measuring the potentiality of firms to develop disruptive innovations (Govindarajan & Kopalle, 2006b). As anticipated by Williamson and Zeng (2004, 2009), Seely Brown and Hagel (2005), Williamson (2010) and Zeng and Williamson (2007) with reference to business models, dis- ruptive innovations are a tool to pre-empt giants from emerging economies that are going global with a new price-performance offering, which is exactly the same purpose of reverse innovation (Immelt, Govindarajan & Trimble, 2009). LGTs that Immelt, Govindarajan and Trimble (2009) and Govindarajan and Trimble (2012) explain as crucial for the development of innovations for emerging economies mirror the spin-off companies described by Christensen and Overdorf (2000), Christensen, Bohmer and DISRUPTIVE INNOVATION . . . IN REVERSE 83 Volume 23 Number 1 2014 © 2013 John Wiley & Sons Ltd Kenagy (2000), Christensen and Raynor (2003) and Danneels (2004, 2006), as the best solution for incumbents that want to compete with or develop disruptive innovations.
  • 43. We therefore believe that disruptive innova- tion theory can be a rich tool for interpreting a subset of reverse innovation as defined by Immelt, Govindarajan and Trimble (2009) and Govindarajan and Trimble (2012). Adopting this perspective, we believe we can enrich the disruptive innovation theory from an emerg- ing country perspective. Geographic Dimension of Disruptive Innovation As discussed in the previous section, it is pos- sible to interpret a subset of reverse innova- tion, and the considerations that follow are limited to this subset, as a particular manifes- tation of disruptive innovation. In fact, Govindarajan and Trimble seem to suggest the same by proposing an uphill flow of reverse innovation to marginalized first and, often, mainstream markets in advanced economies (2012: 22). Can we thus simply generalize the findings and implications of disruptive inno- vation originating from developed countries to situations of reverse innovation? The answer is no. Such a generalization does not work, since success stories of disruptive innovation originating from developed markets differ substantially from success stories that export successful products back to developed markets that were first introduced in emerging economies. Table 2 summarizes the main differences discussed below: • Early market: in disruptive innovation
  • 44. theory, the market segment served by the new technology is characterized by early adopters. In reverse innovation, the early market is instead represented by the large part of the population, or BOP, that has no access to the established technology because it is either too expensive or too complex. This is hardly the case with early adopters and developed markets. These differences should lead to completely different market- ing strategies. • Actors: the small size of the early market in disruptive innovation theory makes spin-off companies or small new entrants the only actors able to serve this market profitably. On the other hand, the vast size of the new market segment to be served in emerging economies allows both local start-ups, foreign MNC subsidiaries and large local companies to make profit from it by exploit- ing economies of scale. The key question is whether local start-ups will find the com- plementary assets to reach international markets. Conversely, there are examples (see the case of Aravind Eye Care in Prahalad, 2004) of successful disruptors in emerging economies which were not able to expand internationally. • Expansion: the evolution of disruptive prod- ucts conceived in and for developed markets brings innovative technologies to commercialization in the same markets as the established ones, while disruptive prod-
  • 45. ucts introduced in and for developing economies allow foreign MNCs and domes- tic companies to export their evolved disruptions to mainstream markets in developed countries, configuring a process of reverse innovation. • Maturation of technology: the technological evolution of disruptive innovations is the same in both cases, but while in disruptive innovation theory this occurs in the same country market, in reverse innovation we see it happening in developing economies and brought to developed economies once the technology has evolved. • Challenges: the development of a technology on a new trajectory puts new entrants in established markets in competition to reach new technological standards. In emerging economies, the main challenge is the diffi- culty of reaching a vast market that often lacks adequate complementary assets (such as distribution and logistics infrastruc- tures). Furthermore, cultural and institu- tional differences make it difficult for foreign firms to understand and properly respond to market needs. • Basis of competition/success: in traditional dis- ruptive innovation theory, the ‘battle’ is won by the company that develops the new tech- nology better and faster, satisfying at first the request for new attributes and, along within technological evolution, catching up on the mainstream attributes. In reverse
  • 46. innovation, competition is instead based on the ability to develop a new business model that allows companies to serve a large portion of the market in order to achieve large sales volumes and economies of scale. Research Propositions and a Research Agenda In light of the discussion presented in this paper, we can conclude that reverse innovation has the potential to take the form of disruptive innovation that originates not from the same geographical market that incumbent compa- nies dominate, but rather from the markets of 84 CREATIVITY AND INNOVATION MANAGEMENT Volume 23 Number 1 2014 © 2013 John Wiley & Sons Ltd T ab le 2. D if fe re n
  • 79. ro d u ct s/ se rv ic es DISRUPTIVE INNOVATION . . . IN REVERSE 85 Volume 23 Number 1 2014 © 2013 John Wiley & Sons Ltd emerging economies, where a technology/ product has been commercialized to fit the characteristics of those markets, particularly serving the vast bottom of the pyramid. The disruptive innovation framework pro- vides us with the dynamics to look at innova- tion that originates for emerging economies. However, the challenges, evolution and factors leading to success or failure of reverse innovation are different from those that are relevant when disruptive innovation originates from a developed market. We therefore argue that instead of simply generalizing the find-
  • 80. ings of disruptive innovation to emerging economies, future studies should take into consideration innovations that originate for those markets. We have thus added a geo- graphical dimension to the disruptive innova- tion paradigm, explaining the variables that should be taken into account when consider- ing such an innovation emerging in develop- ing economies. Given the above considerations we develop four research propositions that we believe may be of inspiration for innovation management scholars and thus fuel future research. Christensen and Raynor (2003) have illus- trated the importance of spin-out companies as a way to overcome the innovator’s dilemma. Incumbents are often disrupted by new entrants because they are not able to see emerging technologies entering the market and to address new needs while improving also on attributes of the technologies adopted by the mainstream market. The establishment of a new autonomous company that rises from an incumbent firm has the potential to respond to the marketing challenge posed by disruptive technologies and to address a new emerging market. Market myopia can also be found in the case of advanced MNCs that operate in emerging markets, often trying to commercialize only small adaptations of their products previously developed for the advanced markets. Hence, the ordination of a subsidiary operating in emerging markets with autonomy regarding product develop-
  • 81. ment can be an important source of reverse innovation with disruptive potential also in advanced markets. RP1: Subsidiaries of ‘advanced’ MNCs in emerging economies can act as the spin-off com- panies theorized by Christensen as a way to overcome the innovator’s dilemma. Scholars should thus focus on organiza- tional and host country factors that may affect subsidiary autonomy as well as its ability to trigger processes of reverse knowledge trans- fer (Ambos, Ambos & Schlegelmilch, 2006). Of particular importance is the role of people appointed to manage the subsidiary. These managers are in fact vectors of innovation stimuli coming from emerging markets. They thus need to know well both the company culture and its technological endowment in order to optimally interpret the best means for product development. At the same time, they need to have enough authority with their headquarters for the ideas they propose that may diverge from the traditional technological path their company follows to be taken into appropriate consideration. In order for companies to be able to trigger reverse innovation processes, two essential conditions need to be present: a strong knowl- edge of emerging market needs and business environment and a good technological base. This is not always the case for a single company. Very often an ‘advanced’ MNC has a
  • 82. strong technological base (given by its experi- ence and the quality of its R&D engineers), but lacks a deep knowledge of emerging markets. On the other hand, ‘emerging’ companies know very well their home market but often lack an appropriate technological base given their relatively short history. RP2: Despite a liberalization trend of emerging economies which allows foreign companies to operate more freely, we will see a new technology-focused generation of joint ventures between ‘advanced’ and ‘emerging’ MNCs. As in the past, the creation of joint ventures and other forms of interaction between foreign and local firms seem to be relevant. But while in the past foreign companies were legally obligated by host country FDI policies to engage in joint ventures in order to get access to the emerging economies’ markets (see, for example, the case of China described by Long, 2005), this need for cooperation may increas- ingly emerge with the aim of merging comple- mentary competences for developing products that are globally marketable. This potential trend suggests a focus on new drivers of cooperation between foreign MNCs and local firms in emerging economies, as they may diverge from previous ones. In particular, we believe it would be interesting to see how R&D teams of such joint ventures are com- posed and what the dynamics occurring between foreign and local engineers are. This intensification of interaction between
  • 83. foreign and local firms in emerging economies can be read and extended from an open inno- vation perspective. RP3: Open innovation dynamics will facilitate the triggering of reverse innovation processes. Future research should try to understand whether and how open innovation dynamics 86 CREATIVITY AND INNOVATION MANAGEMENT Volume 23 Number 1 2014 © 2013 John Wiley & Sons Ltd are different in an emerging economy context. Intuitively, ‘advanced’ MNCs operating in emerging markets can benefit from outbound open innovation performed by local compa- nies that are willing to share or sell their product ideas or nascent technologies for developing and selling them worldwide. This could lead to inbound open innovation per- formed by foreign MNCs which source tech- nologies from local firms or universities and research institutions. Strong intellectual property regimes are required to implement an innovation strategy that is based on an open model. This may be a problem in developing countries since they are shown to have weak intellectual property regimes (IPR) (Zhao, 2006).
  • 84. RP4: As emerging economies will strengthen their intellectual property regimes, we will see more reverse innovation processes. Despite the fact that foreign MNCs are worried about their IP protection in emerging economies, recent contributions show how this problem can be overcome in developing econo- mies such as China (Keupp, Beckenbauer & Gassmann, 2009; Quan & Chesbrough, 2010), presenting successful cases of foreign compa- nies that implement R&D activities in China, providing useful tools for overcoming the risk of IP violation. Future research has the oppor- tunity to study how IP strategies of companies operating in emerging markets will evolve along with the evolution of these countries and how these will probably change, passing from having a local perspective to a more interna- tional or global breadth. An evolved patent system would help researchers to investigate even further the reverse innovation processes by using patents to identify innovations origi- nating from emerging economies which are potentially disruptive, as has already been done for disruptive technologies (Pilkington, Dyerson & Tissier, 2002). In terms of managerial implications, this paper provides companies with a set of basic attributes of reverse innovation with disrup- tive potential. Managers of ‘advanced’ MNCs can thus use these insights to both trigger innovation processes for their own companies, leveraging on their technological basis, or interpret actions underpinned by competitors
  • 85. from emerging economies who are trying to enter foreign advanced markets. Managers of ‘emerging’ MNCs can identify patterns of technology and market development which occurred from an emerging to an advanced market. As reverse innovation dynamics unfold, we expect to see new business models evolve, new forms of interaction between MNCs and local partners, as well as new opportunities for entrepreneurs trying to adapt technologies across distant markets and to explore the role of emerging markets as the new laboratory of the global economy. Note 1. We are aware that an author’s blog is not a strong source but, given the novelty of the topic, the explanation provided in this post is crucial for understanding the concept. References Acee, H.J. (2001) Disruptive Technologies: an Extended View. SM Thesis, Management of Technology, Massachusetts Institute of Technology. Akula, V. (2008) Business Basics at the Base of the Pyramid. Harvard Business Review, 86, 53–57. Ambos, T.C., Ambos, B. and Schlegelmilch, B.B.
  • 86. (2006) Learning from Foreign Subsidiaries: An Empirical Investigation of Headquarters’ Benefits from Reverse Knowledge Transfers. International Business Review, 15, 294–312. Anderson, J.L., Markides, C. and Kupp, M. (2010) The Last Frontier: Market Creation in Conflict Zones, Deep Rural Areas, and Urban Slums. Cali- fornia Management Review, 52, 6–28. Ansari, S., Munir, K. and Gregg, T. (2012) Impact at the ‘Bottom of the Pyramid’: The Role of Social Capital in Capability Development and Commu- nity Empowerment. Journal of Management Studies, 49, 813–42. Anthony, S.D., Eyring, M. and Gibson, L. (2006) Mapping your Innovation Strategy. Harvard Busi- ness Review, 84, 104–13. Bower, J.L. and Christensen, C.M. (1995) Disruptive Technologies: Catching the Wave. Harvard Busi- ness Review, 73, 43–53. Cefis, E. and Marsili, O. (2006) Survivor: The Role of Innovation in Firms’ Survival. Research Policy, 35, 626–41. Charitou, C.D. and Markides, C.C. (2003) Responses to Disruptive Strategic Innovation. MIT Sloan Management Review, 44, 55–63. Chesbrough, H.W. (2002) Environmental Influences upon Firm Entry into New Sub-Markets: Evi- dence from the Worldwide Hard Disk Drive Industry Conditionally. Research Policy, 32, 659–
  • 87. 78. Christensen, C.M. (1997) The Innovator’s Dilemma: When New Technologies Cause Great Firms To Fail. Harvard Business Press, Cambridge, MA. Christensen, C.M. (2006) The Ongoing Process of Building a Theory of Disruption. Journal of Product Innovation Management, 23, 39–55. Christensen, C.M. and Overdorf, M. (2000) Meeting the Challenge of Disruptive Change. Harvard Business Review, 78, 66–76. DISRUPTIVE INNOVATION . . . IN REVERSE 87 Volume 23 Number 1 2014 © 2013 John Wiley & Sons Ltd Christensen, C.M. and Raynor, E.M. (2003) The Inn- ovator’s Solution : Creating and Sustaining Successful Growth. Harvard Business Press, Cambridge, MA. Christensen, C.M., Bohmer, R. and Kenagy, J. (2000) Will Disruptive Innovations Cure Healthcare?
  • 88. Harvard Business Review, 78, 102–12. Christensen, C.M., Johnson, M.W. and Rigby, D.K. (2002) Foundations for Growth. MIT Sloan Man- agement Review, 43, 22–31. Christensen, C.M., Baumann, H., Ruggles, R. and Sadtler, T.M. (2006) Disruptive Innovation for Social Change. Harvard Business Review, 84, 94–101. Corsi, S. and Di Minin, A. (2012) Cina: Da Mercato Emergente a Nuovo Hub di Innovazione? Mondo Cinese, 150, 80–87. Corso, M. and Pellegrini, L. (2007) Continuous and Discontinuous Innovation: Overcoming the Innovator Dilemma. Creativity and Innovation Management, 16, 333–47. Danneels, E. (2004) Disruptive Technology Recon- sidered: A Critique and Research Agenda. The Journal of Product Innovation Management, 21, 246–58.
  • 89. Danneels, E. (2006) Dialogue on the effects of dis- ruptive technology on firms and industries. Journal of Product Innovation Management, 23, 2–4. Di Minin, A. and Bianchi, M. (2011) Safe Nests in Global Nets: Internationalization and Appropriability of R&D in Wireless Telecom. Journal of International Business Studies, 42, 910–34. Garrette, B. and Karnani, A. (2010) Challenges in Marketing Socially Useful Goods to the Poor. California Management Review, 52, 29–47. Gassmann, O. and Han, Z. (2004) Motivations and Barriers of Foreign R&D Activities in China. R&D Management, 34, 423–37. Gilbert, C. (2003) The Disruption Opportunity. MIT Sloan Management Review, 44, 27–32. Gilbert, C. and Bower, J.L. (2002) Disruptive Change. Harvard Business Review, 80, 95–100.
  • 90. Gino, F. and Staats, B.R. (2012) The Microwork Solu- tion. Harvard Business Review, 90, 92–6. Glazer, R. (2007) Meta-Technologies and Innovation Leadership: Why There May Be Nothing New Under the Sun. California Management Review, 50, 120–43. Govindarajan, V. (2009) The Case for ‘Reverse Innovation’ Now. BusinessWeek Online, 26 October. Govindarajan, V. (2012) A Reverse-Innovation Play- book. Harvard Business Review, 90, 120–4. Govindarajan, V. and Trimble, C. (2009) Is Reverse Innovation Like Disruptive Innovation? Harvard Business Review Blog Network [WWW docu- ment]. URL http://blogs.hbr.org/hbr/hbr-now/ 2009/09/is-reverse-innovation-like-dis.html [accessed on 14 June 2012). Govindarajan, V. and Trimble, C. (2012) Reverse Innovation: Create Far from Home, Win Everywhere. Harvard Business Press, Cambridge, MA.
  • 91. Govindarajan, V. and Kopalle, P.K. (2006a) Disrup- tiveness of Innovations: Measurement and an Assessment of Reliability and Validity. Strategic Management Journal, 27, 189–99. Govindarajan, V. and Kopalle, P.K. (2006b) The Use- fulness of Measuring Disruptivenes s of Innova- tions. Ex post in Making ex ante Predictions. Journal of Product Innovation Management, 23, 12–18. Govindarajan, V. and Ramamurti, R. (2011) Reverse Innovation, Emerging Markets and Global Strat- egy. Global Strategy Journal, 1, 191–205. Govindarajan, V., Kopalle, P.K. and Danneels, E. (2011) The Effects of Mainstream and Emerging Customer Orientations on Radical and Disrup- tive Innovations. Journal of Product Innovation Management, 1, 121–32. Hang, C., Chen, J. and Subramanian, A.M. (2010) Developing Disruptive Products for Emerging Economies: Lessons from Asian Cases. Research
  • 92. Technology Management, 53, 21–26. Hart, S.L. and Christensen, C.M (2002) The Great Leap. Driving Innovation from the Base of the Pyramid. MIT Sloan Management Review, 44, 51–6. Henderson, R. (2006) The Innovator’s Dilemma as a Problem of Organizational Competence. Journal of Product Innovation Management, 23, 5–11. Immelt, J.R., Govindarajan, V. and Trimble, C. (2009) How GE is Disrupting Itself. Harvard Business Review, 87, 56–65. Johnson, M.W, Christensen, C.M. and Kagermann, H. (2008) Reinventing your Business Model. Harvard Business Review, 86, 50–9. Johnson, W. (2012) Disrupt Yourself. Harvard Busi- ness Review, 90, 147–50. Kanter, R.M. (2010) Block-by-Blockbuster Innova- tion. Harvard Business Review, 88, 38.
  • 93. Karamchandani, A., Kubzansky, M. and Lalwani, N. (2011) Is the Bottom of the Pyramid Really for You? Harvard Business Review, 89, 107–11. Karnani, A. (2007) The Mirage of Marketing to the Bottom of the Pyramid: How the Private Sector Can Help Alleviate Poverty. California Manage- ment Review, 49, 90–111. Kassicieh, S.K., Kirchhoff, B.A., Walsh, S.T. and McWhorter, P.J. (2002) The Role of Small Firms in the Transfer of Disruptive Technologies. Technovation, 22, 667–74. Kenney, M., Massini, S. and Murtha, T.P. (2009) Offshoring Administrative and Technical Work: New Fields for Understanding the Global Enter- prise. Journal of International Business Studies, 40, 887–900. Keupp, M.M., Beckenbauer, A. and Gassmann, O. (2009) How Managers Protect Intellectual Prop- erty Rights in China Using de facto Strategies. R&D Management, 39, 211–23.
  • 94. London, T. and Hart, S.L. (2004) Reinventing Strat- egies for Emerging Markets: Beyond the Transna- tional Model. Journal of International Business Studies, 35, 350–70. Long, G. (2005) China’s Policies on FDI: Review and Evaluation. In Moran, T., Graham, E.M. and Blomstrom, M. (eds.), Does Foreign Direct Investment Promote Development? Institute for International Economics, Centre for Global Development, Washington, DC, pp. 315–36. Mangelsdorf, M.E. (2009) Good Days for Disruptors. MIT Sloan Management Review, 50, 67–70. 88 CREATIVITY AND INNOVATION MANAGEMENT Volume 23 Number 1 2014 © 2013 John Wiley & Sons Ltd Markides, C. (2006) Disruptive Innovation: In Need of Better Theory. Journal of Product Innovation
  • 95. Management, 23, 19–25. Markides, C.C. (2012) How Disruptive Will Innova- tions from Emerging Markets Be? MIT Sloan Man- agement Review, 54, 23–25. Morris, H., Harvey, C. and Kelly, A. (2009) Journal Rankings and the ABS Journal Quality Guide. Management Decision, 47, 1441–51. O’Reilly III, C.A. and Tushman, M. (2004) The Ambidextrous Organization. Harvard Business Review, 82, 74–81. Olsen, M. and Boxembaum, E. (2009) Bottom of the Pyramid: Organization Barriers to Implementa- tion. California Management Review, 51, 100–25. Patel, P. and Pavitt, K. (1991) Large Firms in the Production of the World’s Technology – An Important Case of Non-Globalization. Journal of International Business Studies, 22, 1–21. Pilkington, A., Dyerson, R. and Tissier, O. (2002) The Electric Vehicle: Patent Data as Indicators of
  • 96. Technological Development. World Patent Infor- mation, 24, 5–12. Prahalad, C.K. (2004) The Fortune at the Bottom of the Pyramid. Eradicating Poverty through Profits. Pearson Education, Harlow. Prahalad, C.K. (2012) Bottom of the Pyramid as a Source of Breakthrough Innovation. Journal of Product Innovation Management, 29, 6–12. Prahalad, C.K. and Hammond, A. (2002) Serving the World’s Poor, Profitably. Harvard Business Review, 80, 48–57. Prahalad, C.K. and Hart, S.L. (2002) The Fortune at the Bottom of the Pyramid. Strategy + Business, 26, 54–67. Quan, X. and Chesbrough, H.W. (2010) Hierarchical Segmentation of R&D Process and Intellectual Property Protection: Evidence from Multinational R&D Laboratories in China. IEEE Transactions on Engineering Management, 57, 9–21.
  • 97. Rafii, F. and Kampas, P.J. (2002) How to Identify your Enemies before they Destroy you. Harvard Business Review, 80, 115–23. Rangan, V.K., Chu, M. and Petkoski, D. (2011) Seg- menting the Base of the Pyramid. Harvard Busi- ness Review, 89, 113–17. Ray, S. and Ray, P.K. (2011) Product Innovation for the People’s Car in an Emerging Economy. Technovation, 31, 216–27. Sandström, C., Magnusson, M. and Jörnmark, J. (2009) Exploring Factors Influencing Incumbents’ Response to Disruptive Innovation. Creativity and Innovation Management, 18, 8–15. Schanz, C., Hüsig, S., Dowling, M. and Gerybadze, A. (2011) ‘Low-Cost High-Tech’ Innovations for China: Why Setting up a Separate R&D Unit is not Always the Best Approach. R&D Management, 41, 307–17. Schmidt, G.M. and Druehl, C.T. (2008) When is a Disruptive Innovation Disruptive? Journal of
  • 98. Product Innovation Management, 25, 347–69. Seelos, C. and Mair, J. (2007) Profitable Business Models and Market Creation in the Context of Deep Poverty: A Strategic View. Academy of Man- agement Perspectives, 21, 49–63. Seely Brown, J. and Hagel III, J. (2005) Inno- vation Blowback: Disruptive Management Practices from Asia. The McKinsey Quarterly, 1, 34–45. Simanis, E. (2012) Reality Check at the Bottom of the Pyramid. Harvard Business Review, 90, 120–5. Simanis, E. and Hart, S. (2009) Innovation from the Inside Out. MIT Sloan Management Review, 50, 77–86. Suzuki, J. and Kodama, F. (2004) Technological Diversity of Persistent Innovators in Japan: Two Case Studies of Large Japanese Firms. Research Policy, 33, 531–49. Utterback, J.M. (2004) The Dynamics of
  • 99. Innovation. Educause Review, January–February, 42–51. Utterback, J.M. and Acee, H.J. (2005) Disruptive Technologies: An Expanded View. International Journal of Innovation Management, 9, 1–17. Vernon, R. (1966) International Investment and International Trade in the Product Cycle. Quar- terly Journal of Economics, 80, 190–207. Von Zedtwitz, M. (2004) Managing Foreign R&D Laboratories in China. R&D Management, 34, 439– 52. Walsh, S.T., Kirchhoff, B.A. and Newbert, S. (2002) Differentiating Market Strategies for Disruptive Technologies. IEEE Transaction on Engineering Management, 49, 341–51. Williamson, P.J. (2010) Cost Innovation: Preparing for a ‘Value-for-Money’ Revolution. Long Range Planning, 43, 343–53. Williamson, P.J. and Zeng, M. (2004) Strategies for
  • 100. Competing in a Changed China. MIT Sloan Man- agement Review, 45, 85–91. Williamson, P.J. and Zeng, M. (2009) Value-for- Money Strategies for Recessionary Times. Harvard Business Review, 87, 66–74. Wood, R.C. and Hamel, G. (2002) The World Bank’s Innovation Market. Harvard Business Review, 80, 104–13. Yu, D. and Hang, C.C. (2010) A Reflective Review of Disruptive Innovation Theory. International Journal of Management Reviews, 12, 435–52. Yu, D. and Hang, C.C. (2011) Creating Technology Candidates for Disruptive Innovation: Generally Applicable R&D Strategies. Technovation, 31, 401– 10. Zeng, M. and Williamson, P.J. (2007) Dragons at your Door: How Chinese Cost Innovation is Disrupting the Rules of Global Competition. Harvard Business School Press, Boston, MA.
  • 101. Zhao, M. (2006) Conducting R&D in Countries with Weak Intellectual Property Rights Protection. Management Science, 52, 1185–99. DISRUPTIVE INNOVATION . . . IN REVERSE 89 Volume 23 Number 1 2014 © 2013 John Wiley & Sons Ltd Simone Corsi ([email protected]) is a post- doctoral researcher at the Institute of Man- agement at the Scuola Superiore Sant’Anna, Pisa, Italy. He has a PhD in Management from the same institution. His research focuses on foreign R&D investment in emerging economies and reverse innova- tion. Simone was one of the 2009 recipients of the Associazione Toscana Cina Insieme Fellowship for his Masters dissertation (‘Relationship Marketing in Chinese Busi- ness to Business’) on Italian investment in China, and he has been Visiting Doctoral student at the Research Center for Global
  • 102. R&D Management at Tongji University, Shanghai. His research interests also include open innovation and disruptive innovation. Alberto Di Minin is an assistant professor at Scuola Superiore Sant’Anna, Pisa, Italy, and Research Fellow at the Berkeley Roundtable on the International Economy (BRIE). He has a PhD from University of California Berkeley. Alberto works with the Istituto di Management at Sant’Anna, and he is an instructor at the Executive School, International School of Advanced Educa- tion (SIAF). His research deals with the appropriability of innovation. He focuses on open innovation, business models, tech- nology transfer, intellectual property and R&D management. On these topics he has published widely in international journals such as Research Policy, California Manage- ment Review, R&D Management and Journal of International Business Studies. Appendix A
  • 103. For our literature review, we used the following procedure. Relying on the Academic Journal Quality Guide (Version 4, 2010) of the Association of Business Schools (Morris, Harvey & Kelly, 2009), we selected Grade Four and Three journals from the following management fields: General Management, International Business, and Innovation (see below for a list of the selected journals). We searched over these journals for papers whose abstracts contained at least one of the following keywords: disruptive innovation, reverse innovation, cost innovation, bottom of the pyramid. We excluded from the resulting articles book reviews and articles whose abstracts contained words composing the keywords put in a different order (hence meaning a different thing). General Management International Business Innovation Academy of Management Review, Academy of Management Journal, Administrative Science Quarterly, Journal of Management, Journal of Management Studies, Harvard Business Review,
  • 104. British Journal of Management, California Management Review, MIT Sloan Management Review, International Journal of Management Reviews, Academy of Management Perspectives, Journal of Management Inquiry Journal of International Business Studies, International Business Review, Management International Review Journal of Product Innovation Management, R&D Management, Technovation The search resulted in 44 total papers. Given the novelty of the topic of innovation from emerging economies, such a low number and concentration of papers in a very limited number of journals is not a surprise. (The papers
  • 105. appeared mainly in practitioner-oriented journals and two innovation management journals. Furthermore, the majority of papers refer to disruptive innovation.) As a further effort, we ran a search using the same keywords over Google Scholar to increase our literature base and especially looking for practical examples. The number of papers grew to 65. The literature we relied on for this paper is schematized in Table 1. 90 CREATIVITY AND INNOVATION MANAGEMENT Volume 23 Number 1 2014 © 2013 John Wiley & Sons Ltd Copyright of Creativity & Innovation Management is the property of Wiley-Blackwell and its content may not be copied or emailed to multiple sites or posted to a listserv without the copyright holder's express written permission. However, users may print, download, or email articles for individual use.
  • 106. Australasian Accounting, Business and Finance Journal Volume 1 Australasian Accounting Business and Finance Journal Issue 2 Australasian Accounting Business and Finance Journal Article 3 Breaking the Paradox of Innovation in Small Businesses through Sustaining and Disruptive Reinvention V. Baard Australian Catholic University T. Watts University of Wollongong, [email protected] Follow this and additional works at: http://ro.uow.edu.au/aabfj Copyright ©2007 Australasian Accounting Business and Finance Journal and Authors.
  • 107. Research Online is the open access institutional repository for the University of Wollongong. For further information contact the UOW Library: [email protected] Recommended Citation Baard, V. and Watts, T., Breaking the Paradox of Innovation in Small Businesses through Sustaining and Disruptive Reinvention, Australasian Accounting , Business and Finance Journal, 1(2), 2007. http://ro.uow.edu.au/?utm_source=ro.uow.edu.au%2Faabfj%2Fv ol1%2Fiss2%2F3&utm_medium=PDF&utm_campaign=PDFCov erPages http://ro.uow.edu.au/?utm_source=ro.uow.edu.au%2Faabfj%2Fv ol1%2Fiss2%2F3&utm_medium=PDF&utm_campaign=PDFCov erPages http://ro.uow.edu.au/aabfj?utm_source=ro.uow.edu.au%2Faabfj %2Fvol1%2Fiss2%2F3&utm_medium=PDF&utm_campaign=PD FCoverPages http://ro.uow.edu.au/aabfj?utm_source=ro.uow.edu.au%2Faabfj %2Fvol1%2Fiss2%2F3&utm_medium=PDF&utm_campaign=PD FCoverPages http://ro.uow.edu.au/aabfj/vol1?utm_source=ro.uow.edu.au%2F aabfj%2Fvol1%2Fiss2%2F3&utm_medium=PDF&utm_campaig n=PDFCoverPages
  • 108. http://ro.uow.edu.au/aabfj/vol1?utm_source=ro.uow.edu.au%2F aabfj%2Fvol1%2Fiss2%2F3&utm_medium=PDF&utm_campaig n=PDFCoverPages http://ro.uow.edu.au/aabfj/vol1/iss2?utm_source=ro.uow.edu.au %2Faabfj%2Fvol1%2Fiss2%2F3&utm_medium=PDF&utm_cam paign=PDFCoverPages http://ro.uow.edu.au/aabfj/vol1/iss2?utm_source=ro.uow.edu.au %2Faabfj%2Fvol1%2Fiss2%2F3&utm_medium=PDF&utm_cam paign=PDFCoverPages http://ro.uow.edu.au/aabfj/vol1/iss2/3?utm_source=ro.uow.edu.a u%2Faabfj%2Fvol1%2Fiss2%2F3&utm_medium=PDF&utm_ca mpaign=PDFCoverPages http://ro.uow.edu.au/aabfj?utm_source=ro.uow.edu.au%2Faabfj %2Fvol1%2Fiss2%2F3&utm_medium=PDF&utm_campaign=PD FCoverPages Breaking the Paradox of Innovation in Small Businesses through Sustaining and Disruptive Reinvention Abstract In 2005 Deloitte Research released a paper examining the phenomenon they refer to as the ‘innovation paradox’: the inability or reluctance of manufacturing firms to
  • 109. pursue strategies that build the operational capabilities necessary for innovation that will provide both profitability and growth. The report claims that this is due to the rapidly increasing complexity of global markets and the lack of synchronising innovation efforts across their value chain, thus positioning the problem as an important contemporary issue. While the research did not specifically target small and medium enterprises, the implications for this business sector are considerable given their substantial contribution to global economies and their high failure rates in the first three to five years of operation. While not questioning the data in the Deloitte research, this paper does question the assumption that the phenomenon is irreversible and the apparent underlying self-fulfilling prophecy with respect to small to medium enterprises. To demonstrate this the authors draw on a case study of a small manufacturing company in rural New South Wales, Australia, which operated between 1889 and 1983, to show that the breaking of the innovation paradox was successfully achieved by this firm in the late nineteenth and early twentieth century. Applying the case study to the Deloitte model the study demonstrates contemporary similarities by overlaying the Laycock history on the successes / failures identified by Deloitte.
  • 110. This article is available in Australasian Accounting, Business and Finance Journal: http://ro.uow.edu.au/aabfj/vol1/iss2/3 http://ro.uow.edu.au/aabfj/vol1/iss2/3?utm_source=ro.uow.edu.a u%2Faabfj%2Fvol1%2Fiss2%2F3&utm_medium=PDF&utm_ca mpaign=PDFCoverPages The Australasian Accounting Business & Finance Journal, May, 2007 Baard and Watts: Breaking the Paradox. Vol. 1, No.2. 25 Breaking the Paradox of Innovation in Small Businesses through Sustaining and Disruptive Reinvention Dr Vicki Baard Discipline of Accounting and Finance, School of Business and Informatics, Australian Catholic University Dr Ted Watts† Discipline of Accounting, School of Accounting and Finance,
  • 111. University of Wollongong ABSTRACT In 2005 Deloitte Research released a paper examining the phenomenon they refer to as the ‘innovation paradox’: the inability or reluctance of manufacturing firms to pursue strategies that build the operational capabilities necessary for innovation that will provide both profitability and growth. The report claims that this is due to the rapidly increasing complexity of global markets and the lack of synchronising innovation efforts across their value chain, thus positioning the problem as an important contemporary issue. While the research did not specifically target small and medium enterprises, the implications for this business sector are considerable given their substantial contribution to global economies and their high failure rates in the first three to five years of operation. While not questioning the data in the Deloitte research, this paper does question the assumption that the phenomenon is irreversible and
  • 112. the apparent underlying self-fulfilling prophecy with respect to small to medium enterprises. To demonstrate this the authors draw on a case study of a small manufacturing company in rural New South Wales, Australia, which operated between 1889 and 1983, to show that the breaking of the innovation paradox was successfully achieved by this firm in the late nineteenth and early twentieth century. Applying the case study to the Deloitte model the study demonstrates contemporary similarities by overlaying the Laycock history on the successes / failures identified by Deloitte. Key words: Small business innovation, reinvention, innovation paradox † Corresponding author. Mail: Building 40. School of Accounting & Finance, University of Wollongong. E-mail: [email protected] * The authors would like to thank the participants of the Emerging Issues in International Accounting Conference for their helpful comments in the development of this paper. The authors retain all responsibility for
  • 113. the arguments presented and their potential errors. INTRODUCTION Deloitte (2005) describes the innovation paradox as the inability or reluctance of manufacturing firms to pursue strategies that build the operational capabilities necessary for innovation to provide both profitability and growth. Their research shows that innovation was the top factor with respect to growth, but the bottom factor with respect to supply chain management. They claim that this is due to the rapidly increasing complexity of global markets and value chains, thus positioning the problem as a contemporary phenomenon. Relating this specifically to small business renowned for innovation, this paper questions the assumptions that this is a contemporary phenomenon and is a self- fulfilling prophecy. To demonstrate this the authors draw on a case study of a small manufacturing company in rural
  • 114. The Australasian Accounting Business & Finance Journal, May, 2007 Baard and Watts: Breaking the Paradox. Vol. 1, No.2. 26 New South Wales, Australia, which operated between 1889 and 1983, to show that the breaking of the innovation paradox was successfully achieved by this firm in the late nineteenth and early twentieth centuries. Applying the case study of Joseph Laycock and Son (Gibson, 1988) to the Deloitte model the study demonstrates contemporary similarities by overlaying the Laycock history on the successes / failures identified by Deloitte. In this way the study demonstrates that by continually reinventing itsel f, this firm successfully avoided the paradox of innovation. THE DELOITTE MODEL The Deloitte model is premised on four critical outcomes of their research. First, that manufacturers must master the complexity of innovation in order to grow; second, that such
  • 115. innovation is driven by changing customer demands and competitive offerings; third, the need to develop a value chain that builds effectively on the market complexities; and finally, the effective management of the entire product lifecycle. From these outcomes Deloitte identified three decisive steps that can be used to generate profitable growth through innovation. The first is the task of creating innovation, the act of generating and evaluating ideas. This involves generating ideas or sourcing concepts from outside the organisation, developing business strategies on which to base investment decisions, recognising and understanding the gap between the performance of existing products that satisfy customer demands and proposed new products, and determining the most appropriate organisational model to put the innovation into practice. The second step is to exploit the innovations created in step one. This involves maximising the innovations growth and profit throughout the product’s entire lifecycle. In particular,
  • 116. ensuring profitability of the product through flexibility of design, thus allowing speedy and inexpensive modifications, together with cost-effective service and other downstream activities. In other words, the business must recognise the enti re value chain. Building innovation capabilities for success is the third step. This involves identification and utilisation of four key factors: • better visibility, both upstream and downstream in the value chain • flexibility in product designs and platforms that allow for quick modifications of product offerings to meet market demands • more extensive collaboration with customers to define product requirements, and with suppliers to design components and new materials • the use of advanced technologies for product lifecycle management, product data management, customer relations management, and advanced
  • 117. planning and scheduling. LITERATURE REVIEW INTRODUCTION Innovation is defined as an application of ideas and knowledge to meet current or future market needs or, more specifically, as the ability of a firm to develop a product to satisfy the future needs of customers (Fitzgerald and Moon, 1996). The difference, while subtle, shifts the focus from market needs to customer needs, and simultaneously from business in general to small business specifically. This is significant because small business innovations in the nineteenth and twentieth centuries have outnumbered big business by two to one (Siropolis, 1997). This is mainly due to the ability of small business to concentrate on new products, The Australasian Accounting Business & Finance Journal, May, 2007
  • 118. Baard and Watts: Breaking the Paradox. Vol. 1, No.2. 27 rather than improving existing products, as is generally the case with big business (Hatten, 2006). While the high failure rate of small businesses is well documented small business have often survived, and indeed flourished, through the process of ‘creative destruction’ or ‘disruptive reinvention’, which constitutes the replacement of existing products, processes and ideas, and of businesses with new and better ones (Hatten, 2006). SUSTAINING AND DISRUPTIVE REINVENTION Fasenfest and Jacobs (2003) document the case of the automotive industry in southeast Michigan, where a rapidly declining manufacturing sector, overly dependent on one sector of industrial production, transformed itself into a revitalised and restructured high-technology business centre. This transformation of a small business sector represented a shift away from manufacturing centres to technical centres that design and build
  • 119. prototypes, make dies, fixtures and machine tools, and assemble automobiles. Similarly, the small businesses of Richmond, Virginia reinvented themselves from support businesses for the traditional banking, tobacco and manufacturing industries to dynamic players in the information technology, semiconductor and biotech industries (Mosher, 2000). The two examples cited above are examples of the changing small business landscape during the Twentieth century, and demonstrate the need for sustainable competitive advantage through reinvention based on disruptive innovation. According to Voelpel, Leibold and Tekie (2004), the focus is on the development of new bases of building strategic competitive advantage in order to outperform competitors and leapfrog into new areas of competitive advantage. However, the strategy of reinvention for small businesses predates the Twentieth century. For example Morgenthaler (1989) reports the case of the Warren Feathbone Co. between 1883 and 1989 and its strategic reinvention. The
  • 120. company, established in 1883, manufactured an elastic boning material from finely split turkey quills, which was used to stiffen and shape corsets, collars and bustles in the ladies clothing industry. However, the company fell victim to changing fashions and the development of plastics and, in 1938, reinvented itself, in collaboration with the B.F. Goodrich Co., into a manufacturer of plastic baby pants. Its second reinvention occurred in the late 1960s and early 1970s, when the era of disposable nappies arrived, reducing the use of cloth nappies, upon which the company relied. This reinvention saw the emergence of a manufacturer of baby clothes, a small thriving business that still exists. The impetus for reinvention is driven by factors within the firm or from the industry of which the firm is part of (Burns, 2001). Such factors include new knowledge (both scientific and non-scientific), the unexpected (unexpected success or failure, or an unexpected event), and changes in perception which might be caused by economic changes, together with societal,
  • 121. cultural and fashion changes. All of these are evident in the cases reviewed above. STRUCTURE OF THE FIRM The above review of reinvention shows that innovative behaviour is influenced by a variety of forces, including the business activity, the industry and the type and structure of the company. Baard (2002) argues that in small businesses the focus of the organising activity is the achievement of an effective and efficient blend of the essential ingredients for organisational success, specifically: people, physical resources and structure. In this respect small businesses have a characteristically flat, flexible structure (Hudson, Smart and Bourne, 2001) comprised of one hierarchical level (Hankinson, Bartlett and Ducheneaut, 1997). The other aspect of structure that appears in both the automobile industry study (Fasenfest and Jacobs, 2003) and the Warren Featherbone study (Morgenthaler, 1989) is the strong
  • 122. The Australasian Accounting Business & Finance Journal, May, 2007 Baard and Watts: Breaking the Paradox. Vol. 1, No.2. 28 relationship between changes in structure and the timing of reinvention. The reinventions of the automobile industry between the 1970s and the 1990s corresponded with important shifts in the development of human capital strategies, including the flattening of the organisation, the transformation from unionised to non-unionised firms, and the replacement of existing management with a more highly educated management team. Likewise, with the Warren Featherbone case, the major innovation reinventions within the company corresponded with generational changes in management. The move into plastic nappies in 1923 occurred with the retirement of the 86 year old founder. This was followed, in 1956, by the firm’s move from Michigan to Georgia, and into general clothing manufacturing, with the founder’s
  • 123. grandson taking control of the business. This was followed in 1976 with the decision by the new vice-president, the founder’s great-grandson, to discontinue the manufacture of general clothing and the move into the manufacture of medium-priced specialist baby clothes. This review, while brief, suggests that small business can adopt competitive strategies that build on its operational capabilities. This is displayed through the firms ability to reinvent itself, and by so doing avoid the paradox of innovation. OVERLAYING THE LAYCOCK STORY BACKGROUND The Laycock story is documented by Gibson (1988) in his thesis Joseph Laycock and Son – Blacksmiths, Engineers and Manufactures 1889-1983, and much of the information is drawn from this work. Joseph Laycock and Son commenced operations in Bathurst, a rural community in Western New South Wales, Australia, in 1889 as a blacksmith’s shop, progressively diversifying into engineering, founding, welding
  • 124. and, in 1918, the manufacture of bagged goods elevators and conveyors for the agricultural industry. With the success of the Laycock Elevator, the company turned to the manufacture of fruit pickers and other small farm equipment, including the patenting and manufacture of a combined cutting and threshing machine in 1922. Following the abolition of bag stacks in favour of bulk grain storage in the 1960s, the viability of chain-type elevators declined, and the Laycock Company ceased elevator production in 1969. However, the other components, such as the light engineering section, expanded, and with the garage, continued until the death of Joe Laycock in 1986 and the closure of the company. CREATING INNOVATION According to the Deloitte (2005, p 9) paper, …manufacturers that are superior at product innovation make it a formal, centralised, step-by-step business process, not a haphazardly