SlideShare a Scribd company logo
Corn, Tomatoes, and a Dead Dog:
Mexican Agricultural Restructuring after
NAFTA and Rural Responses to Declining Maize
Production in Oaxaca, Mexico
Anjali Browning*
University of California, San Diego
This article examines how some of Mexico’s two million small farmers are
responding to the opening of the market for corn. The consequences of
US-Mexican agricultural restructuring include more marginal production
practices, which threaten the nation’s food and water security. Based on
research in San Juan Guelav´ıa, Oaxaca, I argue that even programs imple-
mented to offset the negative impacts of liberalization on small producers
actually undermine them while promoting overexploitation of local
resources. Through case examples, I illustrate the challenges Guelav´ıans face
as they attempt to recreate livelihoods within the context of drought, soil
erosion, resource competition and market exclusion.
Este art´ıculo examina la respuesta de algunos pequen˜os agricultores de
M´exico—que en total suman dos millones—ante la apertura del mercado
del ma´ız. Entre las consecuencias de la reestructuraci´on agr´ıcola M´exico–
Estados Unidos se cuentan m´as pr´acticas marginales de producci´on, que
*This article was developed from a larger dissertation study in Oaxaca, Mexico, sup-
ported by the UCLA Graduate Division and Department of Anthropology, the Garc´ıa
Robles Fulbright program, and the UCSD Center for U.S.–Mexican Studies. I owe
a debt of gratitude to Jeffrey H. Cohen, Alberto D´ıaz-Cayeros, Alejandro Nadal, Kirstin
Appendini, Eric Van Young, Mikael Wolfe, Veronica Castillo Mun˜oz, Flavia Echanove,
Barbara Zepeda Cortes, Rosario Aguilar-Pariente, and Jennifer Piscopo for comments
on earlier drafts of this paper. I also would like to thank the Instituto Tecnol´ogico de
Oaxaca, Rafael Reyes Morales, Juan Juli´an Caballero, Salvador L´opez Platas, and Daniel
Pacheco S´anchez for their help in preparing for and/or conducting this research.
Finally, I would like to thank the many residents of San Juan Guelav´ıa who graciously
gave their time and knowledge.
Mexican Studies/Estudios Mexicanos Vol. 29, Issue 1, Winter 2013, pages 85–119. issn 0742-9797,
electronic issn 1533-8320. ©2013 by The Regents of the University of California. All rights reserved.
Please direct all requests for permission to photocopy or reproduce article content through the
University of California Press’s Rights and Permissions website, at http://www.ucpressjournals.com/
reprint.info.asp. DOI: 10.1525/msem.2013.29.1.85.
85
amenazan la seguridad alimenticia e h´ıdrica de la naci´on. Aqu´ı, sostengo que
en San Juan Guelav´ıa, Oaxaca, incluso los programas implementados para
contrarrestar los impactos negativos de la liberalizaci´on sobre los pequen˜os
productores acaban por socavarlos, al tiempo que promueven la
sobreexplotaci´on de recursos locales. Mediante ejemplos de caso, ilustro los
desaf´ıos que enfrentan los habitantes de Guelav´ıa en sus intentos por recrear
modos de sustento dentro del contexto de la sequ´ıa, la erosi´on de la tierra, la
competencia por los recursos y la exclusi´on del mercado.
Key words: Corn, Depeasantization, Mexico, Migration, NAFTA, Oaxaca,
Peasant Agriculture, Sustainable Farming, Tomatoes, Water.
Palabras clave: ma´ız, descampesinizaci´on, M´exico, migraci´on, TLC, Oaxaca,
agricultura campesina, agricultura sustentable, tomates, agua.
The Problem with Corn: ‘‘¿Est ´as bien o est ´as jodida?’’
During the course of fieldwork in the Zapotec corn-farming town of
San Juan Guelav´ıa, Oaxaca, from 2005 to 2007, I came to realize that I
would not be able to explain much about life in Guelav´ıa without first
addressing corn, water, and migration—for these things preoccupied
every Guelav´ıan. Complaints about failing harvests, low prices,
cheaper corn coming from elsewhere, lack of water, and lack of help
in the fields permeated virtually every interview. A short walk down
any one of Guelav´ıa’s many dirt lanes vividly evidenced the radical
changes that were underway. Crumbling adobe and cane single-room
houses that typified the homes of previous generations were being
increasingly replaced by much larger brick-and-concrete structures
surrounded by fortress-like walls and metal gates. These complexes
were the signposts that invariably demarcated families whose mem-
bers had gone ‘‘al otro lado’’ [to the other side, the United States].
The patchwork of lush corn, withering stalks, and fallow fields that
checkered the surrounding countryside similarly delineated
Guelav´ıa’s corn farmers: those who harvested corn, those who
wanted to harvest corn but could not, and those who no longer tried
to harvest corn. I was reminded of this contrast daily by my host,
Don˜a Esperanza,1
who almost always greeted me at the end of a long
day with a meal simmering over her wood fire and her characteristi-
cally dark-humored salutation, ‘‘¿C´omo est´as? ¿Est´as bien o est´as
jodida, como yo vaya?’’ [How are you? Are you doing well or are
you fucked, like me you know?]
1. Throughout this article, I have used pseudonyms to protect the privacy of study
participants.
86 Mexican Studies/Estudios Mexicanos
Far more than simply the musings of an unusually good-
humored elderly woman, this greeting was an unequivocal statement
about the facts of life in Guelav´ıa. The expected response was not
necessarily that I was doing very well, thank you. Jodida, thanks for
asking, was also a possible and acceptable response to her joke.
Actually, most Guelav´ıans would likely consider themselves to be
jodidos, yet they are also not entirely without hope of doing well.
They are among Mexico’s more than two million2
subsistence and
small farmers who have been hit hard by the agricultural restructur-
ing policies of NAFTA and its neoliberal predecessors. Rather than
accepting their fate, however, they are attempting to respond to their
loss of self-sufficiency, albeit with extremely limited capacities to do
so. Like most small farmers in Mexico, Guelav´ıans can no longer sell
corn even for the cost of planting it. Not surprisingly, some have
altered their production strategies whereas others have sought liveli-
hoods elsewhere, mostly in northern Mexico and the United States.
At the time of my research, one would have been hard pressed to find
a single household that did not have at least one significant family
member who had migrated.
The (un)intended consequences of US-Mexican agricultural re-
structuring include not only the loss of rural livelihoods—what many
refer to as depeasantization,3
—but also generally higher costs of liv-
ing and production, pressure toward outmigration, and greater pres-
sure toward more marginal production practices for virtually all
types of producers who are able to continue cultivating corn, from
highly industrialized commercial producers to subsistence farmers.
Beyond being unfair, many insist that the current pressure on agri-
cultural practices is economically and ecologically unsustainable,
posing a threat to the nation’s food and water security.
The effects of agricultural restructuring have been especially
severe in Mexico’s southern states, such as Oaxaca, where the largest
number of indigenous growers, who are the most marginalized and
undercapitalized producers in the nation, continue to cultivate on
2. Current estimates for the number of Mexican small-scale corn producers range
from 2 to 2.5 million. Depending on sources used, many official estimates state there
are 2.4 million total corn producers (based on applicants for PROCAMPO benefits), of
which 2.2 million are farmers working on plots of less than 10 hectares (ha) (25 acres)
in size and the average producer is farming on plots of less than 2.5 ha. According to
the 1991 census (INEGI 1997), however, there were over 3 million corn-producing
units. For further discussion and comparison of agricultural census data, see Robles
(2010).
3. Among many, see, for example, Deborah Fahy Bryceson (2002), Kjell Havnevik,
et al. (2007), Michael Kearney (1996), Gerardo Otero (1999), and Paola Sesia (2003).
Browning, Mexican Agricultural Restructuring after NAFTA 87
extremely small plots of ejidal land that average from one to two-and-
a-half hectares.4
As I discuss in this article, some government pro-
grams have been implemented to offset the negative impacts of corn
liberalization on such producers, including programs that aid small
farmers in transitioning to new crops such as tomatoes. Based on
ethnographic research conducted in Guelav´ıa, however, I argue that
because of a lack of understanding of economic and ecological con-
straints on production in these regions and how resources are man-
aged within communities based on usos y costumbres, these
programs actually undermine such producers at the same time that
they promote the overexploitation of local resources.
Furthermore, although numerous researchers in Oaxaca have
documented how traditional practices and institutions help many
such indigenous communities to confront or even benefit from glob-
alization processes,5
I found that it is precisely such systems that are
faltering in Guelav´ıa. Community members have less and less to bind
them in mutual interest, which directly impacts their capacity to
respond to failing harvests and rates of resource depletion. A growing
imbalance in the ability of Guelav´ıans to react to economic challenges
is closely related to their unequal access to community lands and
water, to information, to government programs, and to the cash
economy through alternative economic opportunities such as migra-
tion income. As other researchers throughout the general region
have noted,6
and as this research demonstrates, serious conflicts
often arise as capitalist production practices penetrate communities
who continue to try to regulate themselves based on values of com-
munally shared resources.
In the remainder of this article, I first discuss some specific as-
pects of Mexican agrarian restructuring that directly impact produc-
tion practices in rural communities. I then illustrate the particular
4. The large majority of Oaxaca’s corn producers are composed of individual
families—mostly in indigenous communities—farming on extremely small plots of less
than 5 ha (and most often less than 2 ha) for primarily subsistence use, typically uti-
lizing traditional rainfed farming techniques on marginal soils and generating very low
yields when compared with industrialized agricultural standards (INEGI 1997; INEGI
2007; SAGARPA-SIAP 2009).
5. Among the many, consider, for example, the work of Jeffrey Cohen (2004a;
2004b), Lynn Stephen (2007), and Mar´ıa Elena Mart´ınez Torres (2004).
6. See also, for example, the work of Anselmo Arrellanes Meixueiro 2004; Jeffrey
Cohen 2004a; the many contributions in the volume edited by Wayne A. Cornelius and
David Myhre 1998b; Alain de Janvry, Elisabeth Sadoulet, and Jerm´an Gordillo de Anda
1995; Robert M. Emanuel and James B. Greenberg 2000; Jerm´an Gordillo de Anda,
Alain de Janvry, and Elisabeth Sadoulet 1999; June Nash 2004; Monique Nuijten 2004;
Paola Sesia 2003; and Lynn Stephen 2005a; 2005b.
88 Mexican Studies/Estudios Mexicanos
production challenges confronting Guelav´ıans and, like them, most
of Mexico’s small farmers—who make up more than three-quarters of
all of M´exico’s farmers and approximately 90 percent of all M´exico’s
corn producers.7
As I explain, these farmers face challenges on many
fronts: severe ecological conditions such as climate change, drought,
water table depletion, and soil erosion, as well as intense competi-
tion for local resources and extreme exclusion from market institu-
tions. Finally, I present several case examples of community members
or groups who are attempting to re-create livelihoods, including in-
stances in which government programs were utilized to salvage corn
crops or shift to the cultivation of new crops.
The Problem with NAFTA: (Un)intended Consequences
Out of the recognition that suddenly exposing the Mexican corn
market to highly subsidized US corn could irreversibly undercut Mex-
ican producers, accelerate inflation, and fuel widespread migration,
NAFTA architects gave corn one of the longest transition times—four-
teen years as compared with an average of eight years—of all com-
modities included in the agreement. Nevertheless, although tariff
rate quotas (TRQs) were to be applied and gradually reduced over
the length of the transition period, in reality, the market opened
much more rapidly.
Surprisingly, while US exports of corn to M´exico more than tri-
pled by US estimates and more than quadrupled by Mexican esti-
mates from 1994 to 2008,8
and in the same time period real prices
for corn declined by as much as half (and by as much as two-thirds
since the mid-1980s), the Mexican gross production of corn did not
decline.9
Even more surprising for both proponents and critics of
7. See Alain de Janvry, Elisabeth Sadoulet, and Jerm´an Gordillo de Anda 1995 (see
also Kirsten Appendini 2001; Alejandro Nadal 2002; Timothy A. Wise 2010a; 2010b;
Steven Zahniser and William Coyle 2004).
8. Data sources: For US estimates of volume of corn exported to M´exico from
1994 to 2009, see the Foreign Agricultural Trade of the United States (FATUS) database
(USDA ERS 2009) and the USDA Foreign Agricultural Service (FAS) report (USDA FAS
2009). For Mexican estimates of corn imported from the United States, see the
Secretar´ıa de Agricultura, Ganader´ıa, Desarrollo Rural, Pesca y Alimentaci´on—Servicio
de Informaci´on Agroalimenatria y Pesquera (SAGARPA-SIAP) database for Sector
Agroalimentario y Pesquero, Comercio Exterior (SAGARPA-SIAP 2009).
9. Data sources: the Statistical Yearbook 2005–2006, Vol. 1 (FAO 2007), the
FAOSTAT database (FAOSTAT 2009), the GAIN Report: M´exico: Agricultural Situation
(USDA FAS 2004), the SAGARPA-SIAP database, and USDA reports on the state of
Mexican agriculture and corn following NAFTA (Zahniser 2007; Zahniser and Coyle
2004).
Browning, Mexican Agricultural Restructuring after NAFTA 89
NAFTA alike, the total surface area of land dedicated to corn cultiva-
tion actually increased, despite more than two decades of low
prices.10
Most of the yield gains were realized, however, by the largest
industrial growers located primarily in Jalisco and Sinaloa. Among
small and mid-size corn growers, the surface area dedicated to agri-
cultural crops tended to increase, whereas the overall number of
producers and yields decreased (ASERCA 2009; FAO 2007; Nadal
2000; Otero 1999; Robles Berlanga 2010; SAGARPA-SIAP 2009; USDA
FAS 2008; Zahniser and Coyle 2004).11
Some scholars argue that the
discrepancy between yields and area harvested may indicate that with
suppressed prices for corn and for alternative crops, greater numbers
of farmers began putting more marginal lands into production
whereas others moved out of production altogether (see, for exam-
ple, Nadal 2000; 2002; Robles Berlanga 2010; Wise 2010b).
The efficiencies in agricultural production to be gained on both
sides of the border were expected to result primarily from restructur-
ing production to the comparative advantages of each country. This
restructuring involved shifting the majority of capital- and land-
intensive farming to the United States, where mechanized produc-
tion generates high yields on grain crops and shifting labor-intensive
crops to M´exico, such as fruits, vegetables, nuts, and coffee, where
M´exico’s abundant and low-cost labor force would have comparative
price advantages in the export market (Nadal 2000; Wise 2010b).
A critical problem with this agricultural design, however, is that
little thought appears to have been given to the economic and
10. Data sources: For estimates of the amount of ha under cultivation over this
time period, see the FATUS database (USDA ERS 2009), the SAGARPA-SIAP database
(SAGARPA-SIAP 2009), and Robles Berlanga 2010. For analysis and discussion of Mex-
ican and US corn prices over the same time period, see the following publications:
Audley, Papademetriou, et al. 2004; Feiss and Lederman 2004; Puyana and Romero
2004; Y´unez-Naude 2002; and Y´unez-Naude and Barceinas Paredes 2004.
11. The amount of hectares (ha) harvested and yields of corn per ha are well
documented for M´exico in the sources listed, as well as by many others; however, the
actual decline in number of producers since market liberalization began is more dif-
ficult to assess. Steven Zahniser and William Coyle (2004) estimate that the number of
corn producers have decreased by 21 percent; however, this is a difficult statistic to
corroborate across sources. A USDA GAIN report on Mexican grain production con-
firms this trend (USDA FAS 2008). Zahniser and Coyle used the ASERCA database to
determine the number of PROCAMPO beneficiaries who are given subsidies directly
based on plot sizes. The declines in the numbers of producers who have applied for
PROCAMPO benefits are taken to indicate a decline in the number of producers.
Jonathan Fox and Libbey Haight (2010) note, however, that PROCAMPO benefits
actually reach only a minority of small producers; therefore, estimates utilizing PRO-
CAMPO enrollment data drastically underestimate the total number of producers in
Mexico.
90 Mexican Studies/Estudios Mexicanos
ecological sustainability of this restructuring. First, horticultural
crops such as tomatoes reach market saturation much more quickly
than staple crops and cannot be stored until prices improve. They
also have fewer commercial applications in comparison with crops
such as corn, which is used in a multitude of products including feed-
grains, processed foods, plastics, and biofuels. Second, because of
suppressed prices for most agricultural commodities, the majority
of producers began making up for low profit margins by increasing
production through more marginal production practices.12
Finally,
the shift to water-intensive horticultural crops in regions that are
known to be drought prone was dubious at best. Now, as even Mex-
ican commercial corn production has unexpectedly increased, reach-
ing US standards of 8.1 tons per hectare in states such as Sinaloa and
Jalisco, many regions are seeing high degrees of erosion, salinization,
and accumulation of chemical residues; and in regions where irriga-
tion has been heavily utilized, aquifers are exceeding replenishment
rates (Nadal 2000: 7; see also Ackerman et al. 2003). As you will see in
the following examples, many of these problems are surfacing in
small communities such as San Juan Guelav´ıa as well.
The Problem with Corn in San Juan Guelav´ıa:
Environmental, Economic, and Social Challenges to
Production
The dilemma that arises from the loss of self-sufficiency in corn pro-
duction in San Juan Guelav´ıa stems, in part, from the fact that corn is
not merely a product but a way of life. Corn has nourished and
organized the daily lives of community members as far back as any-
one can remember.13
Despite its decline, Guelav´ıans still pride them-
selves on their particular traditions of carefully selecting, cultivating,
preparing, and consuming some of the best-tasting corn in Oaxaca.
Situated on an arid valley floor in the eastern arm of the Valley of
Oaxaca, generations of Guelav´ıans have depended on the saline river,
el Rio Salado, that weaves through their milpa fields to give life to
12. Such as reducing or eliminating crop rotation and fallow periods, reducing
labor-intensive soil and water conservation techniques, employing fertilizers and pes-
ticides, intensifying water extraction, cultivating poorer quality soils, and the like.
13. According to townspeople and colonial documents collected in the national
archives, San Juan Guelav´ıa was originally founded by maize farmers from the nearby
village of Macuilx´ochitl at least as early as the sixteenth century, when it first appears in
colonial documents under the name San Juan Quelaa (Ambrosio Guzm´an and Cruz
Atayde 1999; De Aguilar 1994 [1777]; Garc´ıa Antonio 1999; Hern´andez 1984; Mendieta
y N´un˜ez 1960; Taylor 1972).
Browning, Mexican Agricultural Restructuring after NAFTA 91
their crops when the annual rains flood its channel and disperse its
waters as well as the salt. Nowadays, after more than ten years of
drought, lush cornfields are more often jarringly juxtaposed to with-
ered and brown ones or to abandoned fields left to grow wild. Even
though Guelav´ıa once enjoyed a reputation for fertile alluvial soils
and abundant corn fields, Lucio Mendieta y Nun˜ez (1960) documen-
ted evidence of soil erosion and salinization as early as the 1950s.
This situation has worsened with population growth over time, as
well as with decades of depleted water resources and increased pres-
sure on production. The only fields that continue to thrive inevitably
display the distinctive log-support structures of wells. Even the pres-
ence of wells, however, is no guarantee of a harvest.
The collapse in production that peasant producers are facing is
not due to their inefficiency as capitalists nor to cultural stubborn-
ness, although some would assume that a reluctance to shift produc-
tion to alternative crops indicates a general resistance to innovation
among them. As I will elaborate, the problem with cultivating any
crops in Guelav´ıa is that Guelav´ıans are experiencing a complicated
constellation of ecological, economic, and social constraints on pro-
duction. They lack sufficient water resources; they face rising costs
and risks of production yet low prices; they face intense competition
92 Mexican Studies/Estudios Mexicanos
for resources and markets; they lack access to credit or capital unless
they receive income from off-farm economic activities; and, ironi-
cally, they face labor shortages because of outmigration caused by
the need to subsidize continued corn farming.
Water Table Depletion: Rainfall, Microclimates, Wells, and
Local Competition
Located in the mountain highlands more than 5,500 feet above sea
level in the Isthmus region of southern M´exico, Oaxaca’s weather
patterns are heavily influenced by the mixture of pressure and tem-
perature zones from the Pacific Ocean and the Gulf of M´exico, which
creates what is known as the Mexican summer monsoon.14
The most
critical precipitation period for farmers is the Can´ıcula, however,
a period of midsummer drought that falls within the summer rains,
a phenomenon that makes its strongest impact on M´exico’s southern
region. More importantly, the Can´ıcula fluctuates in timing and dura-
tion and, in recent years, has become less predictable, which greatly
complicates farmers’ abilities to judge rainfall patterns.
According to Don Faustino, a lifelong maize farmer, ‘‘[in
Guelav´ıa] people say that the can´ıcula begins on June 16th . . . and
leaves on August 24th. In the past, it used to rain more. The milpa
could withstand the can´ıcula without extra water and you knew
for sure that after the 24th of August, it was going to begin raining
hard . . . But now we’re not even close to the 24th of August and the
plants aren’t able to withstand it . . . Why? Because it no longer rains
like it should.’’
In addition to unpredictable regional weather patterns, Oaxaca’s
farmers are also affected by a myriad of microclimates as a result of
immense topographic diversity. An important factor in local precip-
itation is a phenomenon known as rain shadow effects from moun-
tain ranges, especially if they are located to the northeast or
southwest, which disrupts prevailing wind flows and hence rainfall.
14. Due to the proximity to the two coasts, precipitation patterns are also subject
to annual fluctuations in El Nin˜o and La Nin˜a weather patterns (Dilley 1996; Magan˜a,
et al. 2003).With a winter El Nin˜o, in which Pacific and Gulf of M´exico currents bring
tropical storms and hurricanes to the coasts, the Valley experiences heavy rains, and,
conversely, in a summer El Nin˜o, the Valley experiences drought (Magan˜a, et al. 2003).
More particularly, El Nin˜o–Southern Oscillation (ENSO) warm current events have
been associated with drought conditions in the Valley of Oaxaca as a result of
a southward displacement of the Inter Tropical Convergence Zone (ITCZ), which re-
duces tropical storms along the coasts (Dilley 1996; Magan˜a, et al. 2003). During La
Nin˜a years, precipitation returns to normal or above average rainfall.
Browning, Mexican Agricultural Restructuring after NAFTA 93
As San Juan Guelav´ıa sits at the base of a mountain chain that runs
along the southern edge of the eastern arm of the Valley, Guelav´ıans
experience drought even when neighboring towns do not. As Don
Faustino insisted, the can´ıcula takes its strongest effect ‘‘primarily in
these towns [here], because from Tule and over there,’’ he pointed
toward the towns to the west, ‘‘there it continues to rain. So, the
can´ıcula is not even [‘‘no es pareja,’’ it is not balanced or fair].’’
Even among farmers who have installed wells, only very few are
still able to grow corn because the underground water table has
diminished. As Don Faustino explained, ‘‘Wells that should have
a water mirror at six meters down at this time of year are now eight
meters down . . . I had a well that measured six meters [earlier this
season] and once I was ready to water the milpa, it didn’t respond.
The aquifers have gone down more.’’15
As wells continue to dry, first
on the agenda of every town-hall meeting (junta), and a topic of
virtually every interview, was the corn harvest crisis. Not only were
wells drying throughout the town and the fields, much of their re-
maining water sources had become brackish.
In addition to reduced rainfall, many Guelav´ıans blame receding
water tables on the fact that the neighboring towns of Tlacocha-
huaya16
and Tlacolula are both making heavy use of underground
water sources in order to produce large volumes of chiles, tomatoes,
and other produce for regional markets. This is considered particu-
larly unjust because those crops require more water, and those other
regions, despite their extremely close proximity, tend to receive more
rain than Guelav´ıa. Curiously, from interviews and conversations
with more than one hundred individuals, not a single person men-
tioned the Benev´a mezcal factory recently built less than a kilometer
from their agricultural lands. The large water demands of such opera-
tions, however, likely place an additional burden on local water
resources.17
15. Quotes taken from recorded interview with Don Faustino, August 10, 2007
(Code: R1_0127.10.2).
16. Tlacochahuaya is the main producer of chiles de agua (water chilies), named
for their high water content.
17. In fact, the factory’s potential impact had not occurred to me either until I
came across an online article criticizing Oaxaca’s governor for reportedly allowing the
exploitation of vast amounts of water resources in several regions of the Valley to be
dedicated to a new mezcal factory recently built under the label Zignum Mezcal. The
factory produces mezcal primarily for export to Europe, Asia, and the United States.
The distillery reportedly consumes great amounts of already depleted water resources
from numerous farming communities in order to eventually produce 45,000 liters of
mezcal daily. Although Benev´a may not be producing at quite this volume, it likely
94 Mexican Studies/Estudios Mexicanos
Thus, Guelav´ıans are facing shortages not only of rainfall and
underground aquifers, but also intense competition for water both
within the community, with neighboring communities producing
increasingly water-intensive crops, and quite possibly with the nearby
mezcal factory. For the most part, only those farmers lucky enough to
have plots close to the river or who have sufficient money to invest in
concrete wells are among the diminishing number who continue to
cultivate their fields fulltime.
Migration and Low Prices
Today, only a very small portion of Guelav´ıa’s population continues
to support themselves primarily on corn cultivation. According to the
national census (INEGI 2000), San Juan Guelav´ıa had 2,940 inhabi-
tants, only 909 of whom were categorized as being of working age.
Out of those, 898 were considered to be employed in some form of
economic activity; of those employed, 446 received only minimum
wage (approximately $50 pesos or US$5 per day) or less for their
efforts, and another 257 were engaged in work for which they did
not receive income, in other words, farmers without alternative
sources of waged income. Virtually all residents must find additional
income, and given the proportion of people earning at or below
minimum wage, migration has become one of few options.
Don Constantino, a lifelong maize farmer in his seventies, fre-
quently reminisced about the old days when there had been so much
rain that they often had to swim with baskets to reach their crops to
harvest the fresh corn. These days, however, there is no such rain, no
such harvest, and no such campesino (small farmer). ‘‘The young
men of today,’’ he lamented, ‘‘they no longer know the sweat of the
campo . . . Now no one works the land, because, for one thing, it no
longer rains as it should, and, for another, the harvest no longer has
the value like in the past. Right now, a lot of maize comes from who
knows where, and they sell it for $2.5 pesos per kilo, and el criollo
[locally ‘‘home-grown’’ maize] we need to sell for $3.5 pesos per kilo.
Nobody wants to buy our criollo maize when so much is transported
here, who knows from where. The little that I work, over there [on
my fields], I have my mazorquita [little bit of corn], but who is going
to buy it? And, who is going to use it also? Because, in the past when
-
places demands on local water resources. See the following online articles from The
Narco News Bulletin (Davies 2010), e-consulta Oaxaca (Guerrero 2009) and Oax-
acaLibre.org (Oaxaca Libre 2007).
Browning, Mexican Agricultural Restructuring after NAFTA 95
my wife was alive she made tortillas and tejate,18
but now, there is
nobody to use the mazorca. Everything is bought now with money.’’
When I asked him if it was still possible to make a living growing
corn, he flatly replied, ‘‘No. No, it is no longer possible to survive by
selling corn alone even though one works very hard. The sellers
[‘‘vendedores,’’ retailers] buy corn from other places, cheaper and
cleaner . . . In the past, people would come [to my house] to buy 30
or 40 almudes.’’ An almud is equivalent to approximately 4 kilos of
shucked corn. Since he sells an almud for $15 pesos (roughly $3.5
pesos per kilo), even 30 almudes represents $450 pesos (approxi-
mately US$45), about half a month’s income based on the average
daily wage in Oaxaca. ‘‘The families that still plant corn do other
things to earn money,’’ he explained. ‘‘In the past, there was nothing
else to dedicate oneself to but the fields. The true campesinos also
harvested garbanzos, black beans, pumpkin seeds, and castor beans
for making lamp oil. These things helped . . . Now everything arrives
from the other side [from somewhere else] and none of those things
help anymore.’’19
In Don Constantino’s explanation of what has happened to corn
production, we hear that Guelav´ıan farmers are unable to compete
with cheaper, preprocessed corn coming from commercial growers
that is transported to the regional markets and even to the towns
‘‘from who knows where.’’ Guelavi´ans’ inability to compete with this
cheaper corn is exacerbated by lack of rain, shifting labor, and
changes in local preparation and consumption of traditional
corn-based products. Yet, although Don Constantino says repeatedly
that there is no maize in the fields and no campesinos growing it, as
I eventually discovered, a ‘‘lack’’ of something for Guelav´ıans does
not always mean its complete absence. Corn does still grow in
Guelav´ıa, campesinos do still work their milpas, and women do still
make tortillas and tejate. None of these practices are, however, per-
formed at a level sufficient enough to sustain a way of life based on
them.
Given such production challenges, an important question to ask
is why do some people continue to harvest corn and others do not
(or cannot)? For those who continue to cultivate corn, how are they
responding to the challenges of production and what are their
options for meeting those challenges? What has been the outcome
18. Tejate is a traditional beverage made from a paste of primarily ground corn
and chocolate.
19. Monograph compiled from recorded interview with Don Constantino, April
16, 2007 (Code: R1_0060.2.2)
96 Mexican Studies/Estudios Mexicanos
for those who have shifted production practices or to other crops
entirely?
Land Distribution: The Dividing Lines of Corn Production in
Guelav´ıa
San Juan Guelav´ıa encompasses 17.86 Km2
of total land, which in-
cludes saline or eroded lands unsuitable for cultivation, privately
held agricultural lands, and 260 hectares (643 acres) of ejidal agricul-
tural lands, which are divided into 503 parcels (INEGI 2007). Out of
these, 44.6 percent (116 hectares/286 acres) are under cultivation;
the remaining 55.4 percent are dedicated for other agricultural uses
such as cattle grazing (INEGI 2007). Although ejidal lands are com-
munally held plots, they are individually worked (INEGI 2007).20
Being a citizen of Guelav´ıa does not guarantee entitlement to an ejido
plot, however. Although some families may have no ejidal lands,
others may have multiple ejidal plots. Furthermore, although ejidal
plots are roughly equal in size—ranging from about 0.5 to 1 hectare
or about 1.25 to 2.5 acres—they can be extremely unequal in shape
and quality, both in terms of soil and location, particularly regarding
access to water.
Regardless of size or quality of lands, ejidal plots are not large
enough to support a family (Hall and Humphrey 2003: 16; Nadal
1999; 2000). Most ejidatarios have private lands as well. Based on
data collected by Jeffrey Cohen from 2000 to 2004 (see Cohen and
Browning 2007), approximately 80 percent of all Guelav´ıan families
continued to farm, utilizing both rainfed and irrigation techniques on
an average of 2.25 hectares (approximately 5.5 acres)—an amount
well in excess of the average ejido plot size—and were able to pro-
duce an average of about six to eight months worth of the maize
needed for daily consumption.21
This indicates that at that time,
20. In anticipation of NAFTA, the Mexican government created a land certification
program known as Programa de Certificaci´on de Derechos Ejidales y Titulaci´on de
Solares Urbanos (PROCEDE). The program was meant to facilitate the process of
privatizing communal lands and to unencumber land-titling procedures more gener-
ally. This process has met with varying responses throughout M´exico. Nevertheless,
Guelav´ıan ejido lands have been measured and certified, although not without con-
tention. It remains unclear how certification will impact how Guelav´ıan lands will
continue to be managed.
21. Based on Mexico’s national average rainfall, according to CEPAL (1982), at
least 4 ha are necessary to produce enough corn for subsistence needs in this region
without some form of irrigation. Therefore, many of Guelav´ıa’s producers would be
considered sub-subsistence producers, and, indeed, most producers tend to diversify
production strategies and household economic strategies to meet their daily needs.
Browning, Mexican Agricultural Restructuring after NAFTA 97
although most families were still continuing to harvest some corn,
even eight years ago, they were not producing surpluses for sale in
the market, and the large majority were well short of what they
needed for their own subsistence despite farming on private as well
as ejido lands.
The extent of the situation was demonstrated to me while I was
seated in an oddly oversized kitchen with Don Jerm´an, a lifelong
maize farmer in his sixties. He said we were sitting in what had once
been his grain room. With a dramatic wave of his hand Don Jerm´an
explained, ‘‘This entire room [about 10 meters long by 4 meters wide
by 4 meters high] used to be filled to the ceiling with maize at this
time of year, and now,’’ he looked despairingly around the huge
room and then pointed to a small pile of dried corn ears in the dark
shadows of the furthest corner, ‘‘now there is nothing but that tiny
pile over there.’’ He concluded that if no rain comes, ‘‘we will all soon
have to abandon the fields.’’22
While most farmers reiterated Don Jerm´an’s complaints about
failing corn harvests, they were in stark contrast to the comments
of a minority of others, such as Don Rom´an who still had ample stores
of maize in his solidly built multistory grain house, which was at least
four times the size of Don Jerm´an’s former grain room. Don Rom´an
insisted that one can still make a living growing maize, albeit with
much more difficulty than in the past. An experienced maize farmer
well into his late fifties, he attributed his good fortune to the fact that
he had both tierra privada (privately owned land) and tierra ejidal
and to his ability to work very hard.23
A bit perplexed, I questioned another town member about how
Don Rom´an was able to generate such a good harvest when others
were not. I was flatly told, with a disdainful snort, that his land was on
the river, which meant he had the best soil and more water without
the need for wells (which drastically reduced his labor and financial
input) and could afford to hire a mozo (helper) to work the fields
because of his good harvest and because he had sons in the United
States sending money as well. I was told that approximately five
families have such lands and such good harvests. The rest must buy
at least some portion of their corn for the year.
The stories of Don Jerm´an and Don Rom´an reveal growing differ-
ences between the farmers who can continue to produce sufficient
22. Monograph compiled from recorded interview with Don Jerm´an, March 9,
2007 (Code: R1_0006.1.0).
23. Monograph compiled from recorded interview with Don Rom´an, April 12,
2007 (Code: R1_0043.1.1-2).
98 Mexican Studies/Estudios Mexicanos
amounts of corn and those who cannot, which has to do not only
with low prices and lack of rain, as Don Constantino told me earlier,
but also with distribution of land, access to water, and access to
migration networks. The patterns of faltering corn production closely
match the patterns of land distribution and access to alternate forms
of income to subsidize the rising costs and risks of production as well
as diminishing returns. Thus, the differences between individual fam-
ily resources, including not only physical resources but also social
resources, profoundly impact the ability of Guelav´ıans to respond to
the challenges in corn production they now face. In this sense, those
who migrate are not necessarily leaving with the intent of abandon-
ing production, but rather, in many cases, they are attempting to save
it. For those who remain in Guelav´ıa and continue to harvest corn,
even with remittance subsidies, production challenges are proving
difficult to overcome.
Rising Costs and Risks of Production
Traditionally, farmers throughout this region have worked their lands
with oxen and plow, relying only on rainfall and alluvial flooding to
water their crops. With severe water shortages, fluctuating corn
prices, and diminishing available family labor as a result of migration,
however, most have had to modify these practices. In Guelav´ıa, those
farmers who can afford to have been employing the use of tractors, in
some cases making use of fertilizers, and installing deep wells along
with a system of pumps and hoses. All of these more intensive farm-
ing technologies place heavier demands on soil and water resources
and are costly, even more so in such marginal and risky conditions.
Unlike US farmers and Mexican commercial growers to the north,
they have no insurance, no price supports, practically no subsidies,
and no access to credit to help offset any of these costs and risks.
Installing a well system can be particularly costly, and, as in the
case of Don Faustino’s well, a well is no guarantee that reliable water
will be obtained. Most farmers, like Don Faustino, dig until they reach
water and then use a system of pumps and hard black plastic hoses.
The cost of digging a dirt well varies depending on if help is hired and
how deep the well must be dug. Pumps alone can cost around $5,000
pesos or US $500. Hose usually costs about $20 pesos per meter, and
an average plot requires, at minimum, a couple hundred meters,
amounting to another $4,000 pesos or more. Dirt wells, especially
when they run deep, can collapse or run dry. The best chance of
keeping water in a well is to install concrete rings, which can easily
cost upward of $100,000 pesos, depending on the well depth. Given
Browning, Mexican Agricultural Restructuring after NAFTA 99
the high cost, only those who have access to migration remittances or
other discretionary funds can afford to install them.
Even for those who do manage to get a consistent water source,
some are still unable to obtain a harvest because of outmigration and
the lack of available help to cultivate fields. Exasperated, Don Faus-
tino once complained that, despite water problems, faltering corn
harvests are not just a result of lack of water because even when it
does rain, few men are preparing their fields.24
Yet, many people,
such as Don Faustino’s son who now lives in Ensenada, have left
largely as a solution to lack of rain and low corn prices as well as to
having few alternative sources of local income. Although they send
money home to help augment family resources, converting those
resources into production is hard if too few able hands are left to
work the land.
The Problem with Innovation: Efforts to Create New
Opportunities in Guelav´ıa
Thus far I have presented numerous obstacles to production; how-
ever, some government subsidies have been made available for rural
development, and numerous community members in San Juan
Guelav´ıa are making use of such funds in an attempt to create new
opportunities in the face of all these odds. Next I describe three
examples of such efforts. All of these projects involved some use of
state and/or federal funds and show how many people are attempting
to cooperate with one another in a manner that is appropriate to
capitalist forms of production. Yet, the mismatch of these efforts with
community understandings of cooperation and competition gener-
ates new tensions. In each case, we can see how engagement with
government-funded projects foments conflict over resources and cre-
ates particular roles for individuals who must coordinate and nego-
tiate the use of funds provided and/or the management of projects
and resources. Furthermore, government agricultural policies largely
dictate the uses to which such funds are put. These policies may not
take into consideration local needs nor the impact on local resources.
The Potable Water Project
In an effort to improve the availability and quality of water for home
consumption, the municipio (town council) undertook to build
24. Based on recorded interview with Don Faustino, March 9, 2007 (Code: R1_
0003-5.1.1-3).
100 Mexican Studies/Estudios Mexicanos
a public water system with a combination of municipal and state
funds. The system is based on a deep well that fills a large storage
tank where the water is sanitized. Access is available to all residents,
provided they can pay to install the piping to connect to the main
line, a tank for home storage, a water meter, and pay for their
monthly usage. Each of the three sections of the town receives water
for two days out of each week. During the two-day period of water
flow, use is restricted only by an individual’s capacity to store it and
ability to pay for it. The municipal water committee, a subcommittee
appointed by the cabildo, controls access to the main line by requir-
ing a permit. Although the permit is free, many say that some com-
mittee members charge unofficial ‘‘fees’’ for the water actually to get
to a resident’s home or land.
Although the potable water project was greatly needed, as many
had been forced to buy water from water trucks during the increas-
ingly protracted dry seasons, many residents also complained that the
new system was depleting the water table and blamed it for wells
drying up throughout the town. On one hand, these criticisms were
lodged against the current presidente and his cabildo administration,
who were a constant focus of critique and reflected a very real con-
cern about the possibility of unsustainable water-table depletion and
the fact that no real measures were being put in place to monitor
excessive usage.
On the other hand, these complaints were also about a new form
of community water management that threatened what little equita-
ble access to community resources might have remained. Since water
had been considered a community resource available to everyone,
the idea that they had to pay for such a resource, that people could
take what water they want as long as they could pay for it, and that
a community resource was being controlled by a few people who
potentially stood to gain from their positions, caused many to be
skeptical about the implementation and/or management of the pro-
ject. For some, the water project was a step toward greater progress,
something that marked them as a modern community; for others, it
provided a badly needed necessity; and for others, it was a necessary
evil. For the latter group, while the system provided more greatly
needed water, it was also a form of attack on communally shared
resources, locking them into expenses for which they must struggle
to find money. Although compatible with a capitalist notion of devel-
opment, one in which access to resources is linked to one’s ability to
acquire them and fairness is ideally regulated by effort—anyone can
access as much water as he or she wants so long as that person puts
forward the initiative to obtain money—the imperative to compete
Browning, Mexican Agricultural Restructuring after NAFTA 101
sets individuals at odds with one another as they have unequal abil-
ities to do so. Such an orientation is incompatible with notions of
equal entitlement to resources.
That said, the large majority did admit that the potable water
project was an improvement for the town and helped meet the needs
of people who have little or no water. Some, who both have milpa
plots close enough to the main line and have the funds necessary,
have been able to use the water for their crops. Others, such as Don
Roberto, told me they would have liked to make use of the new water
for crops but had been unable to take advantage of it for lack of
available capital or for lack of available help in the fields. In Don
Roberto’s case, because he had several sons living in the United States
sending money home, he had enough saved—approximately
$100,000 pesos—to restart his ‘‘alfalfa and corn business’’ by tapping
into the new water source. He felt he could make ‘‘a good living’’
farming multiple plots—except that, because his sons were in the
United States, he had no help in the fields.
Alianza para el Campo y Caja por Caja
One of numerous government funded programs administered
through Alianza para el Campo (Alliance for the Countryside)25
to
provide economic assistance to poor rural communities and to
subsidize livestock production is Caja por Caja (Crate for Crate).
Through this program, qualifying individuals receive a crate of
animals—usually chickens, turkeys, or pigs—in exchange for an
equivalent crate of animals at a later date. The government pays for
half the expense of the original purchase price of the animals, and the
individuals are allowed to raise and breed, sell, or consume the off-
spring. Then on a prespecified date, they return the same number of
animals of equivalent quality, size, and age that they originally
received. Although simple in concept, as Don Faustino explained,
utilizing the program turns out to be a bit more complicated than
it sounds.
A few years earlier, when Don Faustino held a post on the ejido
committee, he worked with this program, which he referred to as
‘‘modalidad dos’’ (second tier). This was how he referred to Alianza’s
25. Since this study was conducted, the name for Alianza para el Campo has been
changed to Activos Productivos. For the purposes of this paper, however, the name of
the program utilized at the time of the study is preserved. For a concise explaination of
Alianza para el Campo, the benefits it offers, and who does or does not receive them,
see Brian Palmer-Rubin 2010.
102 Mexican Studies/Estudios Mexicanos
modalidad PADER. Alianza provides subsidies under two different
tiers (SAGARPA-SIAP 2009).26
The first, modalidad normal (normal
tier), generally provides a smaller proportion of funds, usually 20 to
25 percent of proposed project costs, for rural development (for
example, soils improvements, tractor purchases, greenhouse con-
struction, and the like) to a wider base of beneficiaries. Modalidad
PADER, the second tier, provides a higher proportion of benefits,
usually up to 50 percent of costs but is limited only to those who
qualify under PADER standards.27
Usually Alianza provides funds to those producers who are trying
to develop or augment agricultural and livestock products that it
wishes to promote. Those who wish to secure such aid, regardless
of the tier, must apply through SAGARPA. Because the application
process and providing correct documentation are often the barriers
for inhabitants of poorer communities, numerous individuals ap-
proached Don Faustino to help them secure funds from the caja por
caja program. Unclear about how the process of procuring the funds
and livestock actually works, I asked him how such details are kept
track of. Does someone have a list of the size, weight, and descrip-
tions of the animals? Does that person oversee the delivery and return
of livestock? And how would one go about making the arrangements
for this exchange?
Don Faustino did not seem at all surprised by my dismay. As he
laughed at the tediousness of the idea, he explained, ‘‘Yes, well . . . for
example, if I want to get some chickens, I go down to the government
office [SAGARPA] and they tell me I first need to get three bids on
prices for chickens and then I’ll need to submit an application. So, I
go to some dealers and they each give me a quote. And perhaps I also
ask a few friends or a few women in town, people who know chickens
well, to see what they think of the price. ‘Does the price suit you or
not?’ If it does, then, alright, we’ll go make the contract. And then we
go down to the government office, and there I submit an application
with the credentials of all the people who want to purchase the
chickens along with the credentials of the three dealers and their
26. See the SAGARPA-SIAP website for current and past Reglas de operaci´on de la
Alianza para el Campo (Rules of Operation for Alliance for the Countryside), includ-
ing a description of how benefits are distributed and specific requirements for quali-
fications of beneficiaries (SAGARPA-SIAP 2009).
27. PADER refers to the standards of qualifications for the Programa de De-
sarrollo Rural (Program for Rural Development), which determines the level of under
investment and marginalization of rural communities. Those communities with very
low investment and high levels of marginalization meet the PADER standards, which
qualifies them for increased subsidies for rural development and upliftment.
Browning, Mexican Agricultural Restructuring after NAFTA 103
price quotes. And then that’s it, but it takes a long time, six months or
a year will pass. And, well, if they authorize us, great, or if something
is lacking they don’t authorize us, for some trouble with the require-
ments, or . . . well, they make a study to see if the project is good or
not. Many times they authorize us but many times they do not. For all
the pueblos this happens.’’
Don Faustino went on to describe an example, among many
others, in which he had helped procure some pigs. ‘‘With pigs, they
say a caja is ten female pigs and one male, so a caja is eleven pigs let’s
say. We had arranged for a caja of full-grown pigs, for which one has
to give some $1,500 pesos each, even though they actually cost
$3,000 pesos each . . . The price depends on the type of pig.’’ With
a chuckle he added, ‘‘And you see, here, we know types of pigs like
you know types of cars. There are different qualities of each . . . So, the
government gave us the permission. But then, six months passed and
I hadn’t yet made a decision, as the representative of the people who
wanted the pigs, but that was because the pigs that were approved
were very expensive for them. Each person would have had to pay
$1,000 pesos for each pig, because they were high quality pigs, but,
for the people it didn’t suit them for lack of money . . . I decided to go
to the dealer and explained that the people could not afford these
pigs but the price the government had settled on was already
fixed . . . So, he said he would give us thirty lower quality piglets for
the price of the eleven high-quality adult ones . . . This was much
better for the people because each pig would cost around $200
pesos, so each person would give $100 pesos and the government
would give $100 pesos. Very good . . . So, the dealer made the receipt
for a caja of pigs and we agreed that there were thirty small
pigs . . . and in this way more people benefitted, no?’’
After the dealers receive their payment in full, a delivery date
must then be arranged. Once set by the dealer, the town representa-
tive must go in person to the government office to notify them of the
date. Then a representative from SAGARPA will come on the same day
at the same time to inspect the delivery and the recipients. And then
all the people who are to receive the delivery must also be advised in
person to be there at the same time so, as Don Faustino explained,
‘‘the SAGARPA official can note down what each person received,
note their identification documents, to know who they all are, where
they live, each one has this particular animal and so on. They take
photos, collect all the requirements, and finally all is done. Except
that if it is a caja por caja arrangement, the representative must later
come on the day that is set to collect the caja that is owed in return,
perhaps in six months or, if they are lucky, a year.’’
104 Mexican Studies/Estudios Mexicanos
Shrugging, he surmised, ‘‘So you see, it is like that. And as the
representative, well, it is a matter of losing time, to go and ask, and to
see the items, to get different prices, to make the negotiations, to
submit the applications, to wait for the approval, to organize all the
people, back and forth and back and forth. And, well, I lose these
things [all this time], but it is in order to obtain something for them,
for the people. Good, ok. This is one of the satisfactions of being
a leader, you know, that one feels in representing the people. But
that’s all, no more. Because some people that don’t understand, they
think that someone would take something, that they would make
some earning out of it but no,’’ he tisked in annoyance, ‘‘no, it is not
like that.’’ That people had accused him of taking advantage of his
position to gain from these transactions seemed particularly absurd
to him, given that it would not have even been worth the effort to take
advantage when the gains were so little and the efforts were so
great.28
What we hear from Don Faustino, then, is that while the govern-
ment makes available some aid to small farmers, given the high
degree of undercapitalization in these communities, even paying half
the costs for animals is often too high an investment for cash-poor
individuals. For people who have access to more cash and particu-
larly those who are also knowledgeable about such programs, how-
ever, the potential for increasing their gains is much higher. Clearly,
the gains to be made through purchasing some $20 peso chickens or
$200 peso pigs are quite small, and yet the efforts to obtain them
substantial. In contrast, if one were to invest $1,000 pesos, the effort
is the same but the returns far greater. More importantly though, all
of these gains, no matter how small or big, are fundamentally con-
tingent on one’s ability to access these benefits successfully.
I would like to emphasize here that although the process of
applying for such funds seems nonsensical in its over complication,
many such requirements have been implemented to ensure that ben-
efits reach the people for whom they were intended. All of the exces-
sive receipting, documenting, and identifying of animals and people
were at least presumably put in place to prevent abuses. The real
irony is that potential abusers can still easily find a way around such
procedures, for example, through bribery or through getting various
people to apply for funds on their behalf, whereas the intended
beneficiaries are the ones who ultimately pay the consequences
because the application procedures themselves can become the main
28. Details and quotes in this section compiled from recorded interview with Don
Faustino, April 26, 2007 (Code: R1_0066.4.1).
Browning, Mexican Agricultural Restructuring after NAFTA 105
barrier to receiving such funds. Even for those who are knowledge-
able about applying for such funds and who have the literacy skills to
do so, often just the time and expense of acquiring identification
documents such as proper birth records can cost more in terms of
money and effort than they stand to gain from the subsidies. I would
actually identify lack of documents or lack of correctly and consis-
tently filled-out documents as a crucial obstacle to restructuring pro-
duction efforts, an important issue I take up in greater detail
elsewhere (Browning 2009).
In Don Faustino’s case, he was knowledgeable enough about
working with the government bureaucracy to know the process of
preparing and submitting applications and had all the proper docu-
mentation, but still, there was no guarantee that such funds would be
received. Much time and effort can be spent only to have the appli-
cation be mysteriously denied. Nevertheless, by virtue of necessitat-
ing a negotiator to carry out the transactions, many in the community
suspected that such programs further enabled certain people with
more knowledge and good positioning to gain personally from their
roles. Setting aside the potential pettiness of Don Faustino’s critici-
zers, that someone in his position would try to benefit from his or her
situation is entirely plausible. As we will see in the final example, such
suspicions impact cooperation within group projects as well.
Two Greenhouses, a Bunch of Tomatoes, and a Dead Dog
During a municipal junta in the Spring of 2007,29
numerous outspo-
ken townspeople complained about the preferential help they
believed had been given to an invernadero (greenhouse) project for
growing tomatoes undertaken by Don Faustino and funded through
both the municipal government and Alianza’s Modalidad PADER pro-
gram. Many were upset that the municipio would provide funds and
allow community resources to be used for what was essentially a pri-
vate project. The presidente quickly responded to these complaints
by assuring residents that these benefits were open to anyone in the
community. The government, he explained, will help pay for the
costs of projects by individuals or groups in the town who plan to
produce certain kinds of crops as set forth by Alianza regulations. He
called on all those in attendance to come to the municipio with their
ideas so that they could help them to prepare proposals for funding
as well. The crowd openly scoffed at his offer, both in disbelief that
29. Junta details compiled from recorded meeting and fieldnotes, April 13, 2007
(Code: R1_0055.1; FN-G-10.4.13).
106 Mexican Studies/Estudios Mexicanos
help would materialize and in recognition of the difficulty of coming
up with a viable project. It seemed particularly absurd to them that
the government and the municipio would help with such expensive
and water-intensive projects as greenhouse tomatoes but would not
help salvage their most essential crop: corn. They felt that developing
the deep wells and irrigation that would restore corn crops would
surely require less water than tomatoes. Besides, how many green-
houses could one town support? Residents did not view this
approach as part of a strategy that would benefit all community mem-
bers; rather, it would help only those who had sufficient resources
and connections.
Furthermore, several individuals hotly expressed their concern
about the extensive water demands of growing large volumes of
tomatoes, which would no doubt further deplete the community’s
aquifers. The cabildo justified the use of community resources, how-
ever, because these were the choices the government offered and
because it would provide the community with a locally grown, less-
expensive, and reliable source of tomatoes at the same time that it
would potentially help develop a local industry. As Don Faustino
explained to me, ‘‘The idea was that it could be an example, a test,
to see if we could come up with some kind of secure work, to see if
others in the community should enter into this kind of project, you
know, if the greenhouse turned out to be viable.’’ He even referred to
the project as a commitment between their group, the government,
and the community. Somewhat irritated with community members’
responses to the proposal, he complained, ‘‘Most people just don’t
seem to understand that they too can receive this kind of funding.’’
In fact, two greenhouse projects for growing tomatoes had actu-
ally been initiated by community members and undertaken with sub-
sidies from state government and municipio funds. The two projects
were submitted to SAGARPA through the municipio at more or less
the same time in 2005. After about ten months’ time, both projects
were eventually approved, given that they were the only two projects
that had been submitted for government funding from San Juan
Guelav´ıa.
Although both greenhouse projects were ultimately funded and
built in 2006, they had very different outcomes. These outcomes were
due, in part, to the way in which the greenhouses were managed, as
one was essentially undertaken by one individual, Don˜a Lila, whereas
the other was undertaken by a group of ten individuals, including
Don Faustino and an agronomist from outside San Juan Guelav´ıa.
After some disagreements among members, their group was later
reduced to seven members, six men and one woman.
Browning, Mexican Agricultural Restructuring after NAFTA 107
After assessing the cost of construction for a 300 meter2
green-
house, the state and federal government approved a total cost of
$290,000 pesos (US $29,000) to build each greenhouse, with half of
the costs being paid by the government and the remaining $145,000
pesos being paid, in part, by the municipal government and, in part,
by the individual beneficiaries of each of the projects. As Don˜a Lila
already had the money in place for her share of her project, a little
more than $70,000 pesos after the municipio invested its portion, her
greenhouse was erected first. In the meantime, Don Faustino’s
group, whose members were struggling to come up with their share
of the funds, shopped around for other greenhouse prices. Although
they were required to match the $145,000 peso amount set by the
government, they found a company that would construct a green-
house of considerably larger size, some 500 meters2
, for the same
price but using more economical materials. This increase could
almost double their potential returns. After municipal funds were
contributed, each partner in Don Faustino’s group had to invest
approximately $10,000 pesos (US $1,000) for the greenhouse
construction.
Based on advice from a horticultural and soils engineer, they
selected a variety of hybrid tomato plants that generate very high
yields but are also susceptible to fungi as well as pests. For this rea-
son, both greenhouses required a fairly complex system of double
entry doors and a sanitation room in order to prevent the introduc-
tion of diseases or pests that could induce crop failures. Although
Don Faustino’s group managed to make it through their first growing
season without such catastrophe, Don˜a Lila was not so lucky. Accord-
ing to several community members, her greenhouse suffered large
losses due to contamination. Many speculated this was because she
hired laborers who were not as careful as Don Faustino’s group,
whose members did all the work themselves. Some people even
suspected his group of having sabotaged Don˜a Lila’s project. Accord-
ing to Don Faustino and his partners, however, one of the advantages
of the company that constructed their greenhouse was that it also
provided the plants and offered a guarantee of not only the structure
and water systems, but also the plants. For this reason, they period-
ically sent technicians to inspect the structure and the harvests to
help ensure that the crop was successful. Clearly, this played an
important role in the eventual success of their project relative to the
unfortunate outcome of Don˜a Lila’s.
Nevertheless, Don Faustino’s group did not make it through the
year unscathed. Many differences had arisen within the group. There
were disagreements over who should control the keys to the facilities
108 Mexican Studies/Estudios Mexicanos
and over deciding how resources and labor were to be divided. As
Don Faustino explained, ‘‘One person wanted more order but then
wouldn’t arrive at the time designated. Another, a soils engineer from
outside, criticized the work but didn’t do any of the work himself.
Another didn’t work but always showed up and another didn’t come
at the designated times but worked on his own. And so on.’’30
Although the original agreement among the members was that each
partner would receive an equal share of the tomatoes at harvest,
which they were then entitled to sell as they saw fit, many felt the
input from members had not been equal. Resentment grew among
members over the course of the season about the unequal share of
work performed, and some questioned whether those who had put
in less effort should receive the same share of tomatoes as those who
had put in considerably more effort.
One member in particular had consistently failed to complete his
share of the work. After several aggravating months, once the harvests
were ready, the group informed him that he would be given a smaller
portion of the tomatoes, which they had already set aside for him
after having taken their own shares. Following a particularly heated
argument, he left with his tomatoes in a fit of anger, swearing he
would have nothing more to do with the project. A few days later,
the water pump for the irrigation system became clogged. After
a short investigation, an already putrefied dead dog was discovered
in the greenhouse well. Since the well was tightly covered, the group
was adamant that it could not have been an accident. Although no
one implicated the particular disgruntled individual, everyone clearly
suspected him of the misdeed. With all the widespread complaints
about water use for the greenhouse and the accusations of sabotaging
Don˜a Lila’s greenhouse, however, no one could be certain of the
culprit. Given that a water-source contamination such as a dead dog
presented a serious health problem, the well, the tank, and the entire
hose system had to be purged and disinfected, which required that
someone descend into the well to remove the carcass and clean the
well. The disgust with which Don Faustino described this task made
clear that it had been a difficult situation that left many members of
the group sore. Exasperated with the difficulty of achieving cooper-
ation and the desperate lengths to which people went to undermine
one another, he shook his head, raising his hands in a helpless ges-
ture of resignation, ‘‘How are we going to resolve something like
this?’’
30. Excerpt from recorded interview with Don Faustino, April 26, 2007 (Code:
R1_0067-4.1).
Browning, Mexican Agricultural Restructuring after NAFTA 109
Despite such setbacks, the greenhouse eventually produced
a good crop. By the spring of 2006, the first tomato plants had been
transplanted and by June they began harvesting. Over the three-
month harvest season, the greenhouse churned out almost three tons
of tomatoes, which sold for approximately $15 to $20 pesos per kilo.
As the group was entitled to keep all of the earnings, they managed to
receive a fair return on their investment: they had to invest a com-
bined total of $70,000 pesos to erect the greenhouse and then had to
purchase plants, fertilizers, and pesticides, for which they received
some modest subsidies. Then they put in their labor. They received
a gross return of between $90,000 and $120,000 pesos.31
As the
group felt the endeavor was profitable, they continued planting the
following year.
By mid-summer of 2007, I spoke with Don Faustino after he had
finished tallying up the production for the second season thus far.
‘‘We’re already at three tons and we’re only just reaching halfway
through the harvest season,’’ he proudly smiled. He nodded at my
surprise with satisfaction. ‘‘But there is a difference—’’ he paused for
effect, ‘‘the price,’’ he finally said flatly. ‘‘Last year we sold at $15 to
$20 pesos per kilo, and now,’’ he again paused for effect, ‘‘now we’re
selling at $7 pesos per kilo.’’ They were producing double yet selling
for less than half the price. ‘‘Why? What happened?’’ I asked him.
‘‘Well, you see, it’s that now there’s already many others who are
doing this [growing tomatoes] and there are many that have green-
houses. Practically every pueblo has at least one. And then, there is so
much that arrives here from other places. In other words, there is
competition.’’32
The Problem with Good Intentions
In all of the examples provided, especially in the case of the two
greenhouses, we can surmise that the problem with good intentions
when it comes to agricultural restructuring is that they have many
unintended consequences. Although government funds have been
made available to subsidize the development of horticultural crops
and livestock products that were identified and targeted in the NAFTA
31. As the price fluctuated within the season, between $15 and $20 pesos per kilo,
this range is calculated based on the selling price and volume produced that Don
Faustino provided. He did not tell me a specific number for the gross profit. I’m not
sure they even know an exact gross amount since most of these transactions were
carried out in cash by each individual separately.
32. Excerpt from recorded interview with Don Faustino, July 5, 2007 (Code: R1_
0105.9.1).
110 Mexican Studies/Estudios Mexicanos
agreements to replace faltering corn harvests and aid rural liveli-
hoods, the manner in which these programs have been implemented
has had many unfortunate consequences at the community level.
First, many people neither understand how the government pro-
grams work nor how to access them. This misunderstanding creates
the sense that those who apply for and receive such funds have done
so through illegitimate means. They are suspected of either receiving
advantages by way of favoritism, by way of their position or financial
means, or simply by way of knowing more than others. The erratic
way in which the government approves or denies proposals—which
often has to do with filling quotas for a particular region or other such
bureaucratic considerations—contributes to the perception that
some people get more ‘‘favors’’ through either position or outright
bribery. The variable outcomes of such projects, such as the contam-
ination in Don˜a Lila’s greenhouse versus the lack of contamination in
Don Faustino’s, is again evidence for many of ill-doings in order to
get ahead and yet, at the same time, results from uneven distribution
of information and knowledge. Don Faustino’s group, comprised of
several individuals who were knowledgeable about working with
other government-funded projects, managed to seek out a more
secure arrangement for their project than did Don˜a Lila.
Despite their knowledge of working with such programs and
their experience as farmers, however, these examples demonstrate
the great degree of risk that individuals must undertake in order to
shift to new crops and technologies. This risk is part of the reason
why many individuals, even those who have the resources to under-
take such a project, still prefer to stick with what they know: corn.
Although returns might be low, they stand a better chance of staying
afloat by investing in increased corn production, albeit perhaps on
more marginal land and/or utilizing more marginal production prac-
tices. Furthermore, given corn’s long shelf life and its centrality to the
American diet, farmers can consume what they produce. In contrast,
the quick deterioration of tomatoes makes their cultivation more
risky and their markets more volatile.
Second, work within Don Faustino’s greenhouse group was
extremely difficult to negotiate. Cooperation among partners was
tenuous at best, in large part because each member had equal say
in the management of the project and yet no authority to demand
anything of the others. The only way in which they could enforce
control over others was to band together as a group and deny another
a portion of his or her share. As we have seen, however, this action
may have had dramatic consequences. As Don Faustino once told me,
‘‘People here would prefer to have several quiet enemies than one
Browning, Mexican Agricultural Restructuring after NAFTA 111
loud one’’ or, as it turned out, a dead dog in the well. For someone
like Don Faustino, the application procedures for applying for gov-
ernment funds feel like less of a barrier to getting ahead than do his
own people. Much like George Foster (1967) and Eric Wolf (1957)
long ago argued about closed-corporate communities, great effort
must be exerted to avoid provoking the dangerous consequences
of anger and envy (see also, for example, Greenberg 1989; Kearney
1972; Nader 1964; and Nash 1967). Yet such communities are not
closed. Differences in wealth are increasing rather than being leveled
while community members still attempt to regulate the community
using standards of communally shared resources, which are not nec-
essarily compatible with engagement in private enterprise when they
involve the use of extremely limited community resources. When it
takes place within the parameters of capitalist production, coopera-
tion in such projects feels less like cooperation for the good of the
community and more like individual profiteering utilizing the bene-
fits of ‘‘free’’ community resources.
Third, in the second year of production, as Don Faustino’s toma-
toes were ripening on the vines, the regional price in tomatoes fell
because there had been so much competition in the market for toma-
toes. Although the Mexican government has been promoting the shift
to such horticultural crops through its subsidy programs for campe-
sinos, it has been doing so across the board. Now the glut of tomatoes
produced in the northern states for urban domestic consumption
and export to the north is making its way to the south; at the same
time, locally, practically every town has put in a greenhouse to grow
tomatoes because it is one of the few things for which they can
receive some sort of investment help. And, unlike corn, tomatoes
cannot be stored until a time when the prices might be more favor-
able. Although Don Faustino’s group did still make a profit the sec-
ond year, this was only because they had a much larger harvest than
the first year. For group members, the endeavor was difficult, and
given the price fluctuations of tomatoes, they said they were consid-
ering perhaps growing a different product next time, although no
one was quite sure exactly what.
Finally, the crops such farmers can grow if they wish to transition
away from corn are largely determined by what the government will
help fund. Yet, the government seems to have given little forethought
in the new agricultural plan for M´exico regarding the viability and
sustainability of the crops they have chosen to promote. The focus on
horticultural crops as directed by the terms of NAFTA seems particu-
larly perverted as those crops tend to be so water intensive and are
going to be grown in known drought-prone regions. This poses
112 Mexican Studies/Estudios Mexicanos
particular challenges to local resource management, particularly
because the promotion of such crops has been indiscriminate. The
only way to make up for low prices as these crops reach saturation
point is to produce more of them, demanding even more water re-
sources and further deflating prices because there are virtually no
other alternatives.
Plowing Ahead: Directions for Future Research and
Development
Through the course of this paper, I have shown how corn producers
in San Juan Guelav´ıa face numerous challenges that could be catego-
rized as environmental, economic, social, and political. I have also
shown the ways they have been responding to these challenges. In
some cases, they have attempted to increase production when they
had the ability to do so, generally determined by their access to water,
good land, help, and to off-farm resources such as migration remit-
tances. Such investment has proven extremely risky, however, in the
context of drought, competition for scarce resources, and low crop
prices. In other cases, producers have augmented or abandoned corn
production by shifting to new production strategies and crops such
as the greenhouse projects, although lack of government support in
regulating and stabilizing markets, even for the crops they are pro-
moting to producers, undermines their production efforts and en-
courages increased consumption for scarce water resources. In yet
other cases, farmers have left Guelav´ıa entirely, sometimes to build
a life elsewhere but often to subsidize production for those family
members who have remained at home.
As I stated at the opening of this article, while the picture is bleak
for Guelav´ıan producers, it is not entirely without hope. Were more
concerted effort put into researching and funding crops that can be
sustainably harvested in drought-prone regions, concomitant with
government commitment to regulate, stabilize, and enhance small-
farmer access to markets for their goods, Guelav´ıans could stand
a chance of rebuilding lives and livelihoods. Investigating the viability
of deep wells, reservoirs, and irrigation systems could potentially
help restabilize production if water conservation were also more
closely promoted and regulated. Furthermore, the general paucity
of capital in these regions is a primary barrier to restructuring pro-
duction efforts. Even according to the World Bank, the cost of doing
business in southern M´exico is much higher than anywhere else in
the country, and this is particularly true for small entrepreneurs and
family farms due to ‘‘the scarcity and poor quality of financial services
Browning, Mexican Agricultural Restructuring after NAFTA 113
in the region,’’ which has the lowest bank density in the nation
(Caballero 2003: 13–14). In the World Bank’s findings, only 15 per-
cent of Banca Popular institutions and 5 percent of Mexican com-
mercial banks even operate in the south. Worse, the majority of
money deposited into southern banks tends to be lent out of state,
most often to the federal government for bonds, rather than being
reinvested in the capital-poor farms and small business enterprises
trying to make a living in the south (see also Gordillo de Anda, et al.
1999: 117–131; Myhre 1996: 117–138; 1998: 39–65). Investigating
and developing the potential of micro-banking or simply making
available affordable rural credit could do much to help rural peoples
regain some level of self-sufficiency. Although some subsidies and
other funding have been made available to small farmers, as I have
shown, often the knowledge of such programs and the process of
accessing their benefits are formidable barriers to utilizing them.
Promoting programs in a manner appropriate to regions of high
illiteracy and simplifying the complicated nature of applying for them
is yet another key area of improvement.
Finally, any efforts that are made to investigate and improve rural
livelihoods should take into account local needs and understanding;
otherwise, they are likely to fail. One could argue that rural programs
such as Alianza para el Campo were never really intended to work;
rather, such programs were put in place to placate the poor rural
masses with empty promises and programs. The way in which they
have been implemented, however, not only fails to capitalize produc-
tion, but also undermines the social systems and the resource base of
the communities they were intended to help. Since such programs
are already in place, why not start by making them more effective?
Restoring sustainable rural self-sufficiency to the hands that have long
fed the nation is not simply a matter of good will—I argue it is in the
national self interest. Doing so could help curb the flow of migrants
to the ever-expanding high-risk populations of urban poor and will
help secure the water and food security of the nation for future
generations.
References
Ackerman, Frank, Timothy A. Wise, Kevin P. Gallagher, Luke Ney, and Regina
Flores. 2003. ‘‘Free Trade, Corn, and the Environment: Environmental
Impacts of US – Mexico Corn Trade under NAFTA.’’ Working Paper
No. 03-06: Global Development and Environment Institute, Tufts
University. http://are.berkeley.edu/courses/EEP131/old_files/
AckermanCorn.pdf.
114 Mexican Studies/Estudios Mexicanos
Ambrosio Guzm´an, Liliana V., and Marytza Cruz Atayde. 1999. San Juan
Guelav´ıa: Plan municipal de desarrollo. Thesis, Ciencias en
Planificaci´on de Empresas y Desarrollo Regional. Oaxaca, M´exico:
Instituto Tecnol´ogico de Oaxaca.
Appendini, Kirsten. 2001. De la milpa a los tortibonos:la restructuraci´on dela
pol´ıticaalimentariaenM´exico.M´exico:ElColegiodeM´exico,Institutode
Investigaci´ones de las Naciones Unidas para el Desarollo Social.
Arrellanes Meixueiro, Anselmo. 2004. Conflictos por comunales en el Sur de
M´exico. Presented at ‘‘The Commons in an Age of Global Transition:
Challenges, Risks and Opportunities,’’ the 10th annual conference of the
IASCP, August 9–13. Oaxaca, Oaxaca: International Association for the
Study of Common Property (IASC). www.iascp2004.org.mx (accessed
March 10, 2005).
ASERCA. 2009. Database: Apoyos y Servicios a la Comercializaci´on
Agropecuaria (ASERCA). www.aserca.gob.mx.
Audley, John, Demetrios G. Papademetriou, Sandra Polaski, and Scott
Vaughan. 2004. NAFTA’s Promise and Reality: Lessons from Mexico for
the Hemisphere. Washington, D.C.: Carnegie Endowment for
International Peace.
Browning, Anjali. 2009. South of Hope: The Impacts of US - Mexican
Restructuring and Faltering Corn Production on the Lives of Indigenous
Zapotec Maize Farmers in Oaxaca, Mexico. Doctoral dissertation,
Department of Anthropology. University of California, Los Angeles.
Bryceson, Deborah Fahy. 2002. ‘‘The Scramble in Africa: Reorienting Rural
Livelihoods.’’ World Development 30: 725–739.
Caballero, Jos´e Mar´ıa. 2003. ‘‘Agriculture and Rural Development.’’ In Gill
Hall and Christopher Humphrey (eds.), Mexico Southern States
Development Strategy, Volume 1. Online Report: The World Bank.
http://documents.worldbank.org/curated/en/2003/10/5531347/mexico-
southern-states-development-strategy
CEPAL. 1982. Econom´ıa campesina y agricultura empresarial: tipolog´ıa de
productores del agro Mexicano, M´exico: Siglo XXI. Mexico.
Cohen, Jeffrey H. 2004a. ‘‘Community, Economy and Social Change in
Oaxaca, Mexico: Rural Life and Cooperative Logic in the Global
Economy.’’ In Gerardo Otero (ed.), Mexico in Transition: Neoliberal
Globalism, The State and Civil Society (Globalization and the Semi-
Periphery: Impacts, Opposition, Alternatives), 154–168. London and
New York: Zed Books.
———. 2004b. The Culture of Migration in Southern Mexico. Austin:
University of Texas Press.
Cohen, Jeffrey H., and Anjali Browning. 2007. ‘‘The Decline of a Craft: Basket
MakinginSan JuanGuelav´ıa,Oaxaca.’’ Human Organization 66: 229–239.
Cornelius, Wayne A., and David Myhre (eds.). 1998. The Transformation of
Rural Mexico: Reforming the Ejido Sector. La Jolla: Center for U.S.-
Mexican Studies, University of California, San Diego.
Davies, Nancy. 2010. ‘‘Coca-Cola Moves into Mezcal: Agro-Industry Absorbs
Oaxaca Land and Water for Private Profit, Stainless Steel Vats Replace
Browning, Mexican Agricultural Restructuring after NAFTA 115
Artisanship.’’ The Narco News Bulletin. www.narconews.com/Issue64/
article4045.html (accessed February 27, 2010).
De Aguilar, Fr. Augustin. 1994 [1777]. ‘‘San Juan Teitipac, Tlacolula: Ms.
2450, (No. 92), ff. 199–200v.’’ In Manuel Esparza (ed.), Relaciones
geogr´aficas de Oaxaca: 1777–1778, 309–313. Oaxaca, M´exico: Centro
de Investigaciones y Estudios Superiores en Antropolog´ıa Social
(CIESAS), Instituto Oaxaquen˜o de las Culturas.
De Janvry, Alain, Elisabeth Sadoulet, and Jerm´an Gordillo de Anda. 1995.
‘‘NAFTA and Mexico’s Maize Producers.’’ World Development 23:
1349–1362.
Dilley, Maxx. 1996. ‘‘Synoptic Controls on Precipitation in the Valley of
Oaxaca, Mexico.’’ International Journal of Climatology 16: 1019–1031.
Emanuel, Robert M., and James B. Greenberg. 2000. ‘‘Lluvia Enojada–Tyoo
Kuasi’: The Political Ecology of Forest Extraction in the Sierra Chatina,
Oaxaca.’’ Journal of Political Ecology 7: 43–63.
FAO. 2007. ‘‘FAO Statistical Yearbook 2005–2006, Vol. I.’’ Web Edition: FAO
Statistics Division. www.fao.org/statistics/yearbook (accessed January
16, 2009).
FAOSTAT. 2009. FAO Statistics Division, Database: Food and Agriculture
Organization of the United Nations (FAO). www.faostat.fao.org
(accessed February 16, 2009).
Feiss, Norbert, and Daniel Lederman. 2004. ‘‘Mexican Corn: The Effects of
NAFTA,’’ Trade Note 18, Document No. 32109. Washington, D.C.:
International Trade Department, The World Bank.
Foster, George McClelland. 1967. ‘‘Peasant Society and the Image of Limited
Good.’’ In Jack M.Potter,MayN.Diaz, andGeorge McClelland Foster (eds.),
Peasant Society: A Reader, 300–323. Boston: Little, Brown and Company.
Fox, Jonathan, and Libby Haight (eds.). 2010. Subsidizing Inequality:
Mexican Corn Policy Since NAFTA. Washington DC: Woodrow Wilson
International Center for Scholars.
Garc´ıa Antonio, Epifanio. 1999. Im´agenes de mi pueblo, San Juan Guelav´ıa.
San Juan Guelav´ıa, Tlac., Oaxaca.
Gordillo de Anda, Jerm´an, Alain De Janvry, and Elisabeth Sadoulet. 1999. La
segunda reforma agraria de M´exico: Respuestas de familias y comu-
nidades, 1990–1994. M´exico: Colegio de M´exico: Fideicomiso Historia
de las Am´ericas: Fondo de Cultura Econ´omica.
Greenberg, James B. 1989. Blood Ties: Life and Violence in Rural Mexico.
Tucson: University of Arizona Press.
Guerrero, Jaime. 2009. ‘‘Entra AGP a competencia del mezcal; producir´a 15
mil litros diarios.’’ E-consulta Oaxaca, Noticias. www.e-consulta.com/
oaxaca (accessed February 25, 2010).
Hall, Gill, and Christopher Humphrey. 2003. ‘‘Synthesis Report.’’ In Gill Hall
and Christopher Humphrey (eds.), Mexico Southern States
Development Strategy, Volume 1. Online Report: The World Bank.
Havnevik, Kjell, Deborah Fahy Bryceson, Lars-Erik Birgega˚rd, Prosper
Matondi, and Atakilte Beyene. 2007. ‘‘African Agriculture and the World
116 Mexican Studies/Estudios Mexicanos
Bank: Development or Impoverishment?’’ Nordic African Institute,
Policy Dialogue No.1. Report based on the workshop organized by the
Nordic Africa Institute, Uppala, March 2007. Stockholm, Sweden:
Nordiska Afrikainstitutet (The Nordic Africa Institute).
Hern´andez, Pedro. 1984. Anecdotas narradas por el Sen˜or Pedro Hern´andez
en Zapoteco de San Juan Guelav´ıa y en Espan˜ol. M´exico: Instituto
Lingu¨istico de Verano.
INEGI (Instituto Nacional de Estad´ıstica Geograf´ıa e Informaci´on). 1997. El
ma´ız en el estado de Oaxaca. Aguascalientes, M´exico: Instituto
Nacional de Estad´ıstica Geograf´ıa e Informaci´on (INEGI).
———. 2000. XII Censo general de poblaci´on y vivienda 2000: principales
resultos por localidad, Oaxaca. M´exico: Instituto Nacional de
Estad´ıstica Geograf´ıa e Informaci´on (INEGI). www.inegi.gob.mx.
———. 2007. Programa de Certificaci´on de Derechos Ejidales y Titulaci´on
de Solares, PROCEDE. Oaxaca: abril 1992 – diciembre 2007. Oaxaca,
M´exico: Instituto Nacional de Estad´ıstica Geograf´ıa e Informaci´on
(INEGI).
Kearney, Michael. 1972. The Winds of Ixtepeji: World View and Society in
a Zapotec Town. New York: Holt, Rinehart and Winston, Inc.
———. 1996. Reconceptualizing the Peasantry: Anthropology in Global
Perspective. Boulder, Co.: Westview Press.
Magan˜a, V´ıctor O., Jorge L. V´azquez, Jos´e L. P´erez, and Joel B. P´erez. 2003.
‘‘Impact of El Nin˜o on precipitation in Mexico.’’ Geof´ısica Internacional
42: 313–330.
Mendieta y N´un˜ez, Lucio. 1960. Efectos sociales de la reforma agraria en
tres comunidades ejidales de la Republica Mexicana. M´exico:
Universidad Nacional Aut´onoma de M´exico.
Myhre, David. 1996. ‘‘Appropriate Agricultural Credit: A Missing Piece of
Agrarian Reform in Mexico.’’ In Laura Randall (ed.), Reforming Mexico’s
Agrarian Reform, 117–138. Armonk, NY: M.E. Sharpe.
———. 1998. ‘‘The Achilles’ Heel of the Reforms: The Rural Finance System.’’
In Wayne A. Cornelius and David Myhre (eds.), The Transformation of
Rural Mexico: Reforming the Ejido Sector, 39–65. La Jolla: Center for
U.S.-Mexican Studies, University of California, San Diego.
Nadal, Alejandro. 1999. ‘‘Maize in Mexico. Some Environmental Implications
for the North American Free Trade Agreement (NAFTA).’’ In
Environment and Trade Series, No. 6 — Issue Study 1: Assessing
Environmental Effects of the North American Free Trade Agreement
(NAFTA). Montreal, Canada: Commission for Environmental
Cooperation.
———. 2000. The Environment and Social Impacts of Economic
Liberalization on Corn Production in Mexico. A Study Commissioned
by Oxfam GB and WWF International. Geneva: Oxfam and WWF
International.
———. 2002. Corn in NAFTA: Eight Years After. www.cec.org/files/PDF/
ECONOMY/Corn-NAFTA_en.pdf (accessed February 9, 2008).
Browning, Mexican Agricultural Restructuring after NAFTA 117
Nader, Laura. 1964. Talea and Juquila: A Comparison of Zapotec Social
Organization. Berkeley and New York: University of California Press,
Kraus Reprint (University of California Publications in American
Archaeology and Ethnology, v. 48, no. 3).
Nash, June. 1967. ‘‘Death as a Way of Life: The Increasing Resort to Homicide
in a Mexican Indian Town.’’ American Anthropologist 69: 455–470.
———. 2004. ‘‘Beyond Resistance and Protest: The Maya Quest for
Autonomy.’’ In John M. Watanabe and Edward F. Fischer (eds.),
Pluralizing Ethnography: Comparison and Representation in Maya
Cultures, Histories, and Identities, 163–198. Santa Fe: School of
American Research Press.
Nuijten, Monique. 2004. ‘‘Peasant ‘Participation,’ Rural Property and the
State in Western Mexico.’’ Journal of Peasant Studies 31: 181–209.
Oaxaca Libre. 2007. Pacta URO con Coca Cola explotaci´on de agua
por dinero para campan˜as: APPO. Oaxaca: Oaxaca Libre.
www.oaxacalibre.org (accessed June 5, 2008).
Otero, Gerardo. 1999. Farewell to the Peasantry? Political Class Formation
in Rural Mexico. Boulder, Co.: Westview Press.
Palmer-Rubin, Brian. 2010. ‘‘Is Decentralization the Answer? Lessons from
Alianza para el Campo.’’ In Jonathan Fox and Libby Haight (eds.),
Subsidizing Inequality: Mexican Corn Policy Since NAFTA, 153–161.
Washington, D.C.: Woodrow Wilson International Center for Scholars.
Puyana, Alicia, and Jos´e Romero. 2004. Evaluaci´on integral de los impactos
e instumentaci´on del cap´ıtulo agropecuario del TLCAN. M´exico:
FLACSO and El Colegio de M´exico.
Robles Berlanga, Faustino. 2010. ‘‘A Long-Term View: Comparing the Results
of Mexico’s 1991 and 2007 Agricultural Censuses.’’ In Jonathan Fox and
Libby Haight (eds.), Subsidizing Inequality: Mexican Corn Policy Since
NAFTA, 173–183. Washington, D.C.: Woodrow Wilson International
Center for Scholars.
SAGARPA-SIAP. 2009. Database: Secretaria de Agricultura, Ganader´ıa,
Desarrollo Rural, Pesca y Alimentaci´on (SAGARPA)—Servicio de
Informaci´on Agroalimentaria y Pesquera (SIAP). www.siap.sagarpa.
gob.mx (accessed February 16, 2009).
Sesia, Paola. 2003. ‘‘Repeasantization and Decommodification of Indigenous
Agriculture: Coffee, Corn, and Food Security in Oaxaca.’’ In Casey Walsh,
Lila Emma Ferry, Gabriela Sota Laveaga, Paola Sesia, and Sarah Hill
(eds.), The Social Relations of Mexican Commodities: Power,
Production, and Place. La Jolla, CA: Center for U.S.-Mexican Studies,
University of California, San Diego.
Stephen, Lynn. 2005a. ‘‘Women’s Weaving Cooperatives in Oaxaca: An
Indigenous Response to Neoliberalism.’’ Critique of Anthropology 25:
253–278.
———. 2005b. Zapotec Women: Gender, Class, and Ethnicity in Globalized
Oaxaca. Durham: Duke University Press.
———. 2007. Transborder Lives: Indigenous Oaxacans in Mexico,
California, and Oregon. Durham and London: Duke University Press.
118 Mexican Studies/Estudios Mexicanos
Taylor, William. 1972. Landlord and Peasant in Colonial Oaxaca. Stanford,
CA: Stanford University Press.
Torres, Mar´ıa Elena Mart´ınez. 2004. ‘‘Survival Strategies in Neoliberal
Markets: Peasant Organizations and Organic Coffee in Chiapas.’’ In
Gerardo Otero (ed.), Mexico in Transition: Neoliberal Globalism, the
State and Civil Society (Globalization and the Semi-periphery: Impacts,
Opposition, Alternatives), 169–185. London and New York: Zed Books.
USDA ERS. 2009. Foreign Agricultural Trade of the United States (FATUS)
Database: USDA, Economic Research Service. www.ers.usda.gov/Data/
fatus/ (accessed February 9, 2009).
USDA FAS. 2004. ‘‘GAIN Report: Mexico: Agricultural Situation: Summary of
Mexican Government Study on the Effects of NAFTA on Mexican
Agriculture.’’ GAIN Report No. MX4070: USDA, Foreign Agricultural
Service. www.fas.usda.gov (accessed February 16, 2008).
———. 2008. ‘‘GAIN Report: Mexico: Grain and Feed, Annual Grain and Feed
Report, 2008.’’ GAIN Report No. MX8017: USDA, Foreign Agricultural
Service. www.fas.usda.gov (accessed February 16, 2009).
———. 2009. ‘‘Grain: World Markets and Trade.’’ USDA, Foreign Agricultural
Service. www.fas.usda.gov/grain/circular/2009/01-09/grainfull01-09.pdf
(accessed February 12, 2009).
Wise, Timothy A. 2010a. ‘‘The Costs to Mexican Producers of U.S. Agricultural
Policies.’’ In Mexican Rural Development Research Report, No. 7.
Washington D. C.: Woodrow Wilson International Center for Scholars.
www.wilsoncenter.org/DesarrolloRuralMexicano (accessed June 10, 2012).
———. 2010b. ‘‘The Impacts of U.S. Agricultural Policies on Mexican
Producers.’’ In Jonathan Fox and Libby Haight (eds.), Subsidizing
Inequality: Mexican Corn Policy Since NAFTA: Washington, D.C.:
Woodrow Wilson International Center for Scholars.
Wolf, Eric. 1957. ‘‘Closed Corporate Peasant Communities in Mesoamerica
and Central Java.’’ Southwestern Journal of Anthropology 13: 1–18.
Y´unez-Naude, Antonio. 2002. Lessons from NAFTA: The Case of NAFTA’s
Agricultural Sector. Washington, D.C.: Office of the Chief Economist for
Latin America and the Caribbean, The World Bank.
Y´unez-Naude, Antonio, and Fernando Barceinas Paredes. 2004. The
Agriculture of Mexico After Ten Years of NAFTA Implementation.
Agustinas, Chile: Central Bank of Chile. www.bcentral.cl/eng/stdpub/
studies/workingpaper (accessed March 14, 2008).
Zahniser, Steven. 2007. NAFTA at 13: Implementation Nears Completion.
Document No. WRS-07-01: Economic Research Service, USDA.
www.ers.usda.gov (accessed February 12, 2008).
Zahniser, Steven, and William Coyle. 2004. U.S. - Mexico Corn Trade During
the NAFTA Era: New Twists to an Old Story. Document No. FDS-04D-01:
Economic Research Service, USDA. www.ers.usda.gov (accessed
February 12, 2008).
Browning, Mexican Agricultural Restructuring after NAFTA 119

More Related Content

Viewers also liked

Drenaje vial royyy pdf 123
Drenaje vial royyy pdf 123Drenaje vial royyy pdf 123
Drenaje vial royyy pdf 123
roy becerra
 
CxT Enterprise Company Profile
CxT Enterprise Company ProfileCxT Enterprise Company Profile
CxT Enterprise Company Profile
Trixia Mae Dionisio
 
Manuel #12 y arissa #24
Manuel #12 y arissa #24Manuel #12 y arissa #24
Manuel #12 y arissa #24
Arissa Martinez
 
The Year of the Pitcher: Analyzing No-Hitters
The Year of the Pitcher: Analyzing No-HittersThe Year of the Pitcher: Analyzing No-Hitters
The Year of the Pitcher: Analyzing No-Hitters
Kenneth Burgos
 
Ofimatica
OfimaticaOfimatica
Gure gela hiztegia - eraiketa txokoa
Gure gela hiztegia - eraiketa txokoaGure gela hiztegia - eraiketa txokoa
Gure gela hiztegia - eraiketa txokoa
KIRIKOLATZ
 
LOS SMARTPHONES AGILIZAN EL MERCADO DE COMIDA RAPIDA
LOS SMARTPHONES AGILIZAN EL MERCADO DE COMIDA RAPIDALOS SMARTPHONES AGILIZAN EL MERCADO DE COMIDA RAPIDA
LOS SMARTPHONES AGILIZAN EL MERCADO DE COMIDA RAPIDA
MajoM2003
 
AIG E-Flyer
AIG E-FlyerAIG E-Flyer
AIG E-Flyer
William McLean
 
Grab Chakravorty Heyde and STINS microbial interactions neuronal function 2011
Grab Chakravorty Heyde and STINS microbial interactions neuronal function 2011Grab Chakravorty Heyde and STINS microbial interactions neuronal function 2011
Grab Chakravorty Heyde and STINS microbial interactions neuronal function 2011
Monique Stins, M.A.T., PhD.
 
Dark matter
Dark matterDark matter
Dark matter
Blanca García
 
CBNews SNPTV
CBNews SNPTV CBNews SNPTV
CBNews SNPTV
SNPTV Pub TV
 
A6-Nylon_Film_Handling_Guide_v1
A6-Nylon_Film_Handling_Guide_v1A6-Nylon_Film_Handling_Guide_v1
A6-Nylon_Film_Handling_Guide_v1
Ken Guhse
 
Government final
Government finalGovernment final
Government final
Westyn Swenson
 
Getfeedback 360 degree feedback options
Getfeedback 360 degree feedback optionsGetfeedback 360 degree feedback options
Getfeedback 360 degree feedback options
Abigail Clayton
 
Presentación1
Presentación1Presentación1
Presentación1
cesar martin
 
Gure gela hiztegia - mahai txokoa
Gure  gela  hiztegia - mahai txokoaGure  gela  hiztegia - mahai txokoa
Gure gela hiztegia - mahai txokoa
KIRIKOLATZ
 

Viewers also liked (16)

Drenaje vial royyy pdf 123
Drenaje vial royyy pdf 123Drenaje vial royyy pdf 123
Drenaje vial royyy pdf 123
 
CxT Enterprise Company Profile
CxT Enterprise Company ProfileCxT Enterprise Company Profile
CxT Enterprise Company Profile
 
Manuel #12 y arissa #24
Manuel #12 y arissa #24Manuel #12 y arissa #24
Manuel #12 y arissa #24
 
The Year of the Pitcher: Analyzing No-Hitters
The Year of the Pitcher: Analyzing No-HittersThe Year of the Pitcher: Analyzing No-Hitters
The Year of the Pitcher: Analyzing No-Hitters
 
Ofimatica
OfimaticaOfimatica
Ofimatica
 
Gure gela hiztegia - eraiketa txokoa
Gure gela hiztegia - eraiketa txokoaGure gela hiztegia - eraiketa txokoa
Gure gela hiztegia - eraiketa txokoa
 
LOS SMARTPHONES AGILIZAN EL MERCADO DE COMIDA RAPIDA
LOS SMARTPHONES AGILIZAN EL MERCADO DE COMIDA RAPIDALOS SMARTPHONES AGILIZAN EL MERCADO DE COMIDA RAPIDA
LOS SMARTPHONES AGILIZAN EL MERCADO DE COMIDA RAPIDA
 
AIG E-Flyer
AIG E-FlyerAIG E-Flyer
AIG E-Flyer
 
Grab Chakravorty Heyde and STINS microbial interactions neuronal function 2011
Grab Chakravorty Heyde and STINS microbial interactions neuronal function 2011Grab Chakravorty Heyde and STINS microbial interactions neuronal function 2011
Grab Chakravorty Heyde and STINS microbial interactions neuronal function 2011
 
Dark matter
Dark matterDark matter
Dark matter
 
CBNews SNPTV
CBNews SNPTV CBNews SNPTV
CBNews SNPTV
 
A6-Nylon_Film_Handling_Guide_v1
A6-Nylon_Film_Handling_Guide_v1A6-Nylon_Film_Handling_Guide_v1
A6-Nylon_Film_Handling_Guide_v1
 
Government final
Government finalGovernment final
Government final
 
Getfeedback 360 degree feedback options
Getfeedback 360 degree feedback optionsGetfeedback 360 degree feedback options
Getfeedback 360 degree feedback options
 
Presentación1
Presentación1Presentación1
Presentación1
 
Gure gela hiztegia - mahai txokoa
Gure  gela  hiztegia - mahai txokoaGure  gela  hiztegia - mahai txokoa
Gure gela hiztegia - mahai txokoa
 

Similar to MS2901_05_Corn

Original Sustainability Sen Seminar Final
Original Sustainability Sen Seminar FinalOriginal Sustainability Sen Seminar Final
Original Sustainability Sen Seminar Final
Theresa Fandrei
 
Presentation of SOCLA
Presentation of SOCLAPresentation of SOCLA
Presentation of SOCLA
FAO
 
Vietnamese Immigration Into The United States
Vietnamese Immigration Into The United StatesVietnamese Immigration Into The United States
Vietnamese Immigration Into The United States
Liz Sims
 
Feeding People In Hard Times: What Does Permaculture Have To Offer
Feeding People In Hard Times: What Does Permaculture Have To OfferFeeding People In Hard Times: What Does Permaculture Have To Offer
Feeding People In Hard Times: What Does Permaculture Have To Offer
Fayme4q
 
Permaculture - Feeding People in Hard Times
Permaculture - Feeding People in Hard TimesPermaculture - Feeding People in Hard Times
Permaculture - Feeding People in Hard Times
Farrah85p
 
WATER POLLUTION.docx
WATER POLLUTION.docxWATER POLLUTION.docx
WATER POLLUTION.docx
melbruce90096
 
Extended Reading Review Extended Reading Review CriteriaRati.docx
Extended Reading Review Extended Reading Review CriteriaRati.docxExtended Reading Review Extended Reading Review CriteriaRati.docx
Extended Reading Review Extended Reading Review CriteriaRati.docx
ssuser454af01
 
Feeding People in Hard Times: What Does Permaculture Have to Offer
Feeding People in Hard Times: What Does Permaculture Have to OfferFeeding People in Hard Times: What Does Permaculture Have to Offer
Feeding People in Hard Times: What Does Permaculture Have to Offer
School Vegetable Gardening - Victory Gardens
 
Conservation You Can Taste: Heritage Seed Saving
Conservation You Can Taste: Heritage Seed SavingConservation You Can Taste: Heritage Seed Saving
Conservation You Can Taste: Heritage Seed Saving
Seeds
 
Conservation You Can Taste: Heritage Seed Saving
Conservation You Can Taste: Heritage Seed SavingConservation You Can Taste: Heritage Seed Saving
Conservation You Can Taste: Heritage Seed Saving
School Vegetable Gardening - Victory Gardens
 
Think Globally Eat Locally Final Report 8-23-08 | American Farmland Trust
Think Globally Eat Locally Final Report 8-23-08 | American Farmland TrustThink Globally Eat Locally Final Report 8-23-08 | American Farmland Trust
Think Globally Eat Locally Final Report 8-23-08 | American Farmland Trust
American Farmland Trust
 
Manifesto on the Future of Seeds
Manifesto on the Future of SeedsManifesto on the Future of Seeds
Manifesto on the Future of Seeds
Seeds
 
Research Synopsis
Research SynopsisResearch Synopsis
Research Synopsis
Ina ZL
 
Food and Prosperity: Balancing Technology and Community in Agriculture
Food and Prosperity: Balancing Technology and Community in AgricultureFood and Prosperity: Balancing Technology and Community in Agriculture
Food and Prosperity: Balancing Technology and Community in Agriculture
The Rockefeller Foundation
 
Food & Prosperity: Balancing Technology and Community in Agriculture
Food & Prosperity: Balancing Technology and Community in AgricultureFood & Prosperity: Balancing Technology and Community in Agriculture
Food & Prosperity: Balancing Technology and Community in Agriculture
The Rockefeller Foundation
 
2005 10-farm-natural-habitat
2005 10-farm-natural-habitat2005 10-farm-natural-habitat
2005 10-farm-natural-habitat
Angel F. Rojas
 
8th may,2020 daily global regional and local rice e newsletter(1)
8th may,2020 daily global regional and local rice e newsletter(1)8th may,2020 daily global regional and local rice e newsletter(1)
8th may,2020 daily global regional and local rice e newsletter(1)
Riceplus Magazine
 
8th may,2020 daily global regional and local rice e newsletter
8th may,2020 daily global regional and local rice e newsletter8th may,2020 daily global regional and local rice e newsletter
8th may,2020 daily global regional and local rice e newsletter
Riceplus Magazine
 
8th may,2020 daily global regional and local rice e newsletter(1)
8th may,2020 daily global regional and local rice e newsletter(1)8th may,2020 daily global regional and local rice e newsletter(1)
8th may,2020 daily global regional and local rice e newsletter(1)
Riceplus Magazine
 
8th may,2020 daily global regional and local rice e newsletter
8th may,2020 daily global regional and local rice e newsletter8th may,2020 daily global regional and local rice e newsletter
8th may,2020 daily global regional and local rice e newsletter
Riceplus Magazine
 

Similar to MS2901_05_Corn (20)

Original Sustainability Sen Seminar Final
Original Sustainability Sen Seminar FinalOriginal Sustainability Sen Seminar Final
Original Sustainability Sen Seminar Final
 
Presentation of SOCLA
Presentation of SOCLAPresentation of SOCLA
Presentation of SOCLA
 
Vietnamese Immigration Into The United States
Vietnamese Immigration Into The United StatesVietnamese Immigration Into The United States
Vietnamese Immigration Into The United States
 
Feeding People In Hard Times: What Does Permaculture Have To Offer
Feeding People In Hard Times: What Does Permaculture Have To OfferFeeding People In Hard Times: What Does Permaculture Have To Offer
Feeding People In Hard Times: What Does Permaculture Have To Offer
 
Permaculture - Feeding People in Hard Times
Permaculture - Feeding People in Hard TimesPermaculture - Feeding People in Hard Times
Permaculture - Feeding People in Hard Times
 
WATER POLLUTION.docx
WATER POLLUTION.docxWATER POLLUTION.docx
WATER POLLUTION.docx
 
Extended Reading Review Extended Reading Review CriteriaRati.docx
Extended Reading Review Extended Reading Review CriteriaRati.docxExtended Reading Review Extended Reading Review CriteriaRati.docx
Extended Reading Review Extended Reading Review CriteriaRati.docx
 
Feeding People in Hard Times: What Does Permaculture Have to Offer
Feeding People in Hard Times: What Does Permaculture Have to OfferFeeding People in Hard Times: What Does Permaculture Have to Offer
Feeding People in Hard Times: What Does Permaculture Have to Offer
 
Conservation You Can Taste: Heritage Seed Saving
Conservation You Can Taste: Heritage Seed SavingConservation You Can Taste: Heritage Seed Saving
Conservation You Can Taste: Heritage Seed Saving
 
Conservation You Can Taste: Heritage Seed Saving
Conservation You Can Taste: Heritage Seed SavingConservation You Can Taste: Heritage Seed Saving
Conservation You Can Taste: Heritage Seed Saving
 
Think Globally Eat Locally Final Report 8-23-08 | American Farmland Trust
Think Globally Eat Locally Final Report 8-23-08 | American Farmland TrustThink Globally Eat Locally Final Report 8-23-08 | American Farmland Trust
Think Globally Eat Locally Final Report 8-23-08 | American Farmland Trust
 
Manifesto on the Future of Seeds
Manifesto on the Future of SeedsManifesto on the Future of Seeds
Manifesto on the Future of Seeds
 
Research Synopsis
Research SynopsisResearch Synopsis
Research Synopsis
 
Food and Prosperity: Balancing Technology and Community in Agriculture
Food and Prosperity: Balancing Technology and Community in AgricultureFood and Prosperity: Balancing Technology and Community in Agriculture
Food and Prosperity: Balancing Technology and Community in Agriculture
 
Food & Prosperity: Balancing Technology and Community in Agriculture
Food & Prosperity: Balancing Technology and Community in AgricultureFood & Prosperity: Balancing Technology and Community in Agriculture
Food & Prosperity: Balancing Technology and Community in Agriculture
 
2005 10-farm-natural-habitat
2005 10-farm-natural-habitat2005 10-farm-natural-habitat
2005 10-farm-natural-habitat
 
8th may,2020 daily global regional and local rice e newsletter(1)
8th may,2020 daily global regional and local rice e newsletter(1)8th may,2020 daily global regional and local rice e newsletter(1)
8th may,2020 daily global regional and local rice e newsletter(1)
 
8th may,2020 daily global regional and local rice e newsletter
8th may,2020 daily global regional and local rice e newsletter8th may,2020 daily global regional and local rice e newsletter
8th may,2020 daily global regional and local rice e newsletter
 
8th may,2020 daily global regional and local rice e newsletter(1)
8th may,2020 daily global regional and local rice e newsletter(1)8th may,2020 daily global regional and local rice e newsletter(1)
8th may,2020 daily global regional and local rice e newsletter(1)
 
8th may,2020 daily global regional and local rice e newsletter
8th may,2020 daily global regional and local rice e newsletter8th may,2020 daily global regional and local rice e newsletter
8th may,2020 daily global regional and local rice e newsletter
 

MS2901_05_Corn

  • 1. Corn, Tomatoes, and a Dead Dog: Mexican Agricultural Restructuring after NAFTA and Rural Responses to Declining Maize Production in Oaxaca, Mexico Anjali Browning* University of California, San Diego This article examines how some of Mexico’s two million small farmers are responding to the opening of the market for corn. The consequences of US-Mexican agricultural restructuring include more marginal production practices, which threaten the nation’s food and water security. Based on research in San Juan Guelav´ıa, Oaxaca, I argue that even programs imple- mented to offset the negative impacts of liberalization on small producers actually undermine them while promoting overexploitation of local resources. Through case examples, I illustrate the challenges Guelav´ıans face as they attempt to recreate livelihoods within the context of drought, soil erosion, resource competition and market exclusion. Este art´ıculo examina la respuesta de algunos pequen˜os agricultores de M´exico—que en total suman dos millones—ante la apertura del mercado del ma´ız. Entre las consecuencias de la reestructuraci´on agr´ıcola M´exico– Estados Unidos se cuentan m´as pr´acticas marginales de producci´on, que *This article was developed from a larger dissertation study in Oaxaca, Mexico, sup- ported by the UCLA Graduate Division and Department of Anthropology, the Garc´ıa Robles Fulbright program, and the UCSD Center for U.S.–Mexican Studies. I owe a debt of gratitude to Jeffrey H. Cohen, Alberto D´ıaz-Cayeros, Alejandro Nadal, Kirstin Appendini, Eric Van Young, Mikael Wolfe, Veronica Castillo Mun˜oz, Flavia Echanove, Barbara Zepeda Cortes, Rosario Aguilar-Pariente, and Jennifer Piscopo for comments on earlier drafts of this paper. I also would like to thank the Instituto Tecnol´ogico de Oaxaca, Rafael Reyes Morales, Juan Juli´an Caballero, Salvador L´opez Platas, and Daniel Pacheco S´anchez for their help in preparing for and/or conducting this research. Finally, I would like to thank the many residents of San Juan Guelav´ıa who graciously gave their time and knowledge. Mexican Studies/Estudios Mexicanos Vol. 29, Issue 1, Winter 2013, pages 85–119. issn 0742-9797, electronic issn 1533-8320. ©2013 by The Regents of the University of California. All rights reserved. Please direct all requests for permission to photocopy or reproduce article content through the University of California Press’s Rights and Permissions website, at http://www.ucpressjournals.com/ reprint.info.asp. DOI: 10.1525/msem.2013.29.1.85. 85
  • 2. amenazan la seguridad alimenticia e h´ıdrica de la naci´on. Aqu´ı, sostengo que en San Juan Guelav´ıa, Oaxaca, incluso los programas implementados para contrarrestar los impactos negativos de la liberalizaci´on sobre los pequen˜os productores acaban por socavarlos, al tiempo que promueven la sobreexplotaci´on de recursos locales. Mediante ejemplos de caso, ilustro los desaf´ıos que enfrentan los habitantes de Guelav´ıa en sus intentos por recrear modos de sustento dentro del contexto de la sequ´ıa, la erosi´on de la tierra, la competencia por los recursos y la exclusi´on del mercado. Key words: Corn, Depeasantization, Mexico, Migration, NAFTA, Oaxaca, Peasant Agriculture, Sustainable Farming, Tomatoes, Water. Palabras clave: ma´ız, descampesinizaci´on, M´exico, migraci´on, TLC, Oaxaca, agricultura campesina, agricultura sustentable, tomates, agua. The Problem with Corn: ‘‘¿Est ´as bien o est ´as jodida?’’ During the course of fieldwork in the Zapotec corn-farming town of San Juan Guelav´ıa, Oaxaca, from 2005 to 2007, I came to realize that I would not be able to explain much about life in Guelav´ıa without first addressing corn, water, and migration—for these things preoccupied every Guelav´ıan. Complaints about failing harvests, low prices, cheaper corn coming from elsewhere, lack of water, and lack of help in the fields permeated virtually every interview. A short walk down any one of Guelav´ıa’s many dirt lanes vividly evidenced the radical changes that were underway. Crumbling adobe and cane single-room houses that typified the homes of previous generations were being increasingly replaced by much larger brick-and-concrete structures surrounded by fortress-like walls and metal gates. These complexes were the signposts that invariably demarcated families whose mem- bers had gone ‘‘al otro lado’’ [to the other side, the United States]. The patchwork of lush corn, withering stalks, and fallow fields that checkered the surrounding countryside similarly delineated Guelav´ıa’s corn farmers: those who harvested corn, those who wanted to harvest corn but could not, and those who no longer tried to harvest corn. I was reminded of this contrast daily by my host, Don˜a Esperanza,1 who almost always greeted me at the end of a long day with a meal simmering over her wood fire and her characteristi- cally dark-humored salutation, ‘‘¿C´omo est´as? ¿Est´as bien o est´as jodida, como yo vaya?’’ [How are you? Are you doing well or are you fucked, like me you know?] 1. Throughout this article, I have used pseudonyms to protect the privacy of study participants. 86 Mexican Studies/Estudios Mexicanos
  • 3. Far more than simply the musings of an unusually good- humored elderly woman, this greeting was an unequivocal statement about the facts of life in Guelav´ıa. The expected response was not necessarily that I was doing very well, thank you. Jodida, thanks for asking, was also a possible and acceptable response to her joke. Actually, most Guelav´ıans would likely consider themselves to be jodidos, yet they are also not entirely without hope of doing well. They are among Mexico’s more than two million2 subsistence and small farmers who have been hit hard by the agricultural restructur- ing policies of NAFTA and its neoliberal predecessors. Rather than accepting their fate, however, they are attempting to respond to their loss of self-sufficiency, albeit with extremely limited capacities to do so. Like most small farmers in Mexico, Guelav´ıans can no longer sell corn even for the cost of planting it. Not surprisingly, some have altered their production strategies whereas others have sought liveli- hoods elsewhere, mostly in northern Mexico and the United States. At the time of my research, one would have been hard pressed to find a single household that did not have at least one significant family member who had migrated. The (un)intended consequences of US-Mexican agricultural re- structuring include not only the loss of rural livelihoods—what many refer to as depeasantization,3 —but also generally higher costs of liv- ing and production, pressure toward outmigration, and greater pres- sure toward more marginal production practices for virtually all types of producers who are able to continue cultivating corn, from highly industrialized commercial producers to subsistence farmers. Beyond being unfair, many insist that the current pressure on agri- cultural practices is economically and ecologically unsustainable, posing a threat to the nation’s food and water security. The effects of agricultural restructuring have been especially severe in Mexico’s southern states, such as Oaxaca, where the largest number of indigenous growers, who are the most marginalized and undercapitalized producers in the nation, continue to cultivate on 2. Current estimates for the number of Mexican small-scale corn producers range from 2 to 2.5 million. Depending on sources used, many official estimates state there are 2.4 million total corn producers (based on applicants for PROCAMPO benefits), of which 2.2 million are farmers working on plots of less than 10 hectares (ha) (25 acres) in size and the average producer is farming on plots of less than 2.5 ha. According to the 1991 census (INEGI 1997), however, there were over 3 million corn-producing units. For further discussion and comparison of agricultural census data, see Robles (2010). 3. Among many, see, for example, Deborah Fahy Bryceson (2002), Kjell Havnevik, et al. (2007), Michael Kearney (1996), Gerardo Otero (1999), and Paola Sesia (2003). Browning, Mexican Agricultural Restructuring after NAFTA 87
  • 4. extremely small plots of ejidal land that average from one to two-and- a-half hectares.4 As I discuss in this article, some government pro- grams have been implemented to offset the negative impacts of corn liberalization on such producers, including programs that aid small farmers in transitioning to new crops such as tomatoes. Based on ethnographic research conducted in Guelav´ıa, however, I argue that because of a lack of understanding of economic and ecological con- straints on production in these regions and how resources are man- aged within communities based on usos y costumbres, these programs actually undermine such producers at the same time that they promote the overexploitation of local resources. Furthermore, although numerous researchers in Oaxaca have documented how traditional practices and institutions help many such indigenous communities to confront or even benefit from glob- alization processes,5 I found that it is precisely such systems that are faltering in Guelav´ıa. Community members have less and less to bind them in mutual interest, which directly impacts their capacity to respond to failing harvests and rates of resource depletion. A growing imbalance in the ability of Guelav´ıans to react to economic challenges is closely related to their unequal access to community lands and water, to information, to government programs, and to the cash economy through alternative economic opportunities such as migra- tion income. As other researchers throughout the general region have noted,6 and as this research demonstrates, serious conflicts often arise as capitalist production practices penetrate communities who continue to try to regulate themselves based on values of com- munally shared resources. In the remainder of this article, I first discuss some specific as- pects of Mexican agrarian restructuring that directly impact produc- tion practices in rural communities. I then illustrate the particular 4. The large majority of Oaxaca’s corn producers are composed of individual families—mostly in indigenous communities—farming on extremely small plots of less than 5 ha (and most often less than 2 ha) for primarily subsistence use, typically uti- lizing traditional rainfed farming techniques on marginal soils and generating very low yields when compared with industrialized agricultural standards (INEGI 1997; INEGI 2007; SAGARPA-SIAP 2009). 5. Among the many, consider, for example, the work of Jeffrey Cohen (2004a; 2004b), Lynn Stephen (2007), and Mar´ıa Elena Mart´ınez Torres (2004). 6. See also, for example, the work of Anselmo Arrellanes Meixueiro 2004; Jeffrey Cohen 2004a; the many contributions in the volume edited by Wayne A. Cornelius and David Myhre 1998b; Alain de Janvry, Elisabeth Sadoulet, and Jerm´an Gordillo de Anda 1995; Robert M. Emanuel and James B. Greenberg 2000; Jerm´an Gordillo de Anda, Alain de Janvry, and Elisabeth Sadoulet 1999; June Nash 2004; Monique Nuijten 2004; Paola Sesia 2003; and Lynn Stephen 2005a; 2005b. 88 Mexican Studies/Estudios Mexicanos
  • 5. production challenges confronting Guelav´ıans and, like them, most of Mexico’s small farmers—who make up more than three-quarters of all of M´exico’s farmers and approximately 90 percent of all M´exico’s corn producers.7 As I explain, these farmers face challenges on many fronts: severe ecological conditions such as climate change, drought, water table depletion, and soil erosion, as well as intense competi- tion for local resources and extreme exclusion from market institu- tions. Finally, I present several case examples of community members or groups who are attempting to re-create livelihoods, including in- stances in which government programs were utilized to salvage corn crops or shift to the cultivation of new crops. The Problem with NAFTA: (Un)intended Consequences Out of the recognition that suddenly exposing the Mexican corn market to highly subsidized US corn could irreversibly undercut Mex- ican producers, accelerate inflation, and fuel widespread migration, NAFTA architects gave corn one of the longest transition times—four- teen years as compared with an average of eight years—of all com- modities included in the agreement. Nevertheless, although tariff rate quotas (TRQs) were to be applied and gradually reduced over the length of the transition period, in reality, the market opened much more rapidly. Surprisingly, while US exports of corn to M´exico more than tri- pled by US estimates and more than quadrupled by Mexican esti- mates from 1994 to 2008,8 and in the same time period real prices for corn declined by as much as half (and by as much as two-thirds since the mid-1980s), the Mexican gross production of corn did not decline.9 Even more surprising for both proponents and critics of 7. See Alain de Janvry, Elisabeth Sadoulet, and Jerm´an Gordillo de Anda 1995 (see also Kirsten Appendini 2001; Alejandro Nadal 2002; Timothy A. Wise 2010a; 2010b; Steven Zahniser and William Coyle 2004). 8. Data sources: For US estimates of volume of corn exported to M´exico from 1994 to 2009, see the Foreign Agricultural Trade of the United States (FATUS) database (USDA ERS 2009) and the USDA Foreign Agricultural Service (FAS) report (USDA FAS 2009). For Mexican estimates of corn imported from the United States, see the Secretar´ıa de Agricultura, Ganader´ıa, Desarrollo Rural, Pesca y Alimentaci´on—Servicio de Informaci´on Agroalimenatria y Pesquera (SAGARPA-SIAP) database for Sector Agroalimentario y Pesquero, Comercio Exterior (SAGARPA-SIAP 2009). 9. Data sources: the Statistical Yearbook 2005–2006, Vol. 1 (FAO 2007), the FAOSTAT database (FAOSTAT 2009), the GAIN Report: M´exico: Agricultural Situation (USDA FAS 2004), the SAGARPA-SIAP database, and USDA reports on the state of Mexican agriculture and corn following NAFTA (Zahniser 2007; Zahniser and Coyle 2004). Browning, Mexican Agricultural Restructuring after NAFTA 89
  • 6. NAFTA alike, the total surface area of land dedicated to corn cultiva- tion actually increased, despite more than two decades of low prices.10 Most of the yield gains were realized, however, by the largest industrial growers located primarily in Jalisco and Sinaloa. Among small and mid-size corn growers, the surface area dedicated to agri- cultural crops tended to increase, whereas the overall number of producers and yields decreased (ASERCA 2009; FAO 2007; Nadal 2000; Otero 1999; Robles Berlanga 2010; SAGARPA-SIAP 2009; USDA FAS 2008; Zahniser and Coyle 2004).11 Some scholars argue that the discrepancy between yields and area harvested may indicate that with suppressed prices for corn and for alternative crops, greater numbers of farmers began putting more marginal lands into production whereas others moved out of production altogether (see, for exam- ple, Nadal 2000; 2002; Robles Berlanga 2010; Wise 2010b). The efficiencies in agricultural production to be gained on both sides of the border were expected to result primarily from restructur- ing production to the comparative advantages of each country. This restructuring involved shifting the majority of capital- and land- intensive farming to the United States, where mechanized produc- tion generates high yields on grain crops and shifting labor-intensive crops to M´exico, such as fruits, vegetables, nuts, and coffee, where M´exico’s abundant and low-cost labor force would have comparative price advantages in the export market (Nadal 2000; Wise 2010b). A critical problem with this agricultural design, however, is that little thought appears to have been given to the economic and 10. Data sources: For estimates of the amount of ha under cultivation over this time period, see the FATUS database (USDA ERS 2009), the SAGARPA-SIAP database (SAGARPA-SIAP 2009), and Robles Berlanga 2010. For analysis and discussion of Mex- ican and US corn prices over the same time period, see the following publications: Audley, Papademetriou, et al. 2004; Feiss and Lederman 2004; Puyana and Romero 2004; Y´unez-Naude 2002; and Y´unez-Naude and Barceinas Paredes 2004. 11. The amount of hectares (ha) harvested and yields of corn per ha are well documented for M´exico in the sources listed, as well as by many others; however, the actual decline in number of producers since market liberalization began is more dif- ficult to assess. Steven Zahniser and William Coyle (2004) estimate that the number of corn producers have decreased by 21 percent; however, this is a difficult statistic to corroborate across sources. A USDA GAIN report on Mexican grain production con- firms this trend (USDA FAS 2008). Zahniser and Coyle used the ASERCA database to determine the number of PROCAMPO beneficiaries who are given subsidies directly based on plot sizes. The declines in the numbers of producers who have applied for PROCAMPO benefits are taken to indicate a decline in the number of producers. Jonathan Fox and Libbey Haight (2010) note, however, that PROCAMPO benefits actually reach only a minority of small producers; therefore, estimates utilizing PRO- CAMPO enrollment data drastically underestimate the total number of producers in Mexico. 90 Mexican Studies/Estudios Mexicanos
  • 7. ecological sustainability of this restructuring. First, horticultural crops such as tomatoes reach market saturation much more quickly than staple crops and cannot be stored until prices improve. They also have fewer commercial applications in comparison with crops such as corn, which is used in a multitude of products including feed- grains, processed foods, plastics, and biofuels. Second, because of suppressed prices for most agricultural commodities, the majority of producers began making up for low profit margins by increasing production through more marginal production practices.12 Finally, the shift to water-intensive horticultural crops in regions that are known to be drought prone was dubious at best. Now, as even Mex- ican commercial corn production has unexpectedly increased, reach- ing US standards of 8.1 tons per hectare in states such as Sinaloa and Jalisco, many regions are seeing high degrees of erosion, salinization, and accumulation of chemical residues; and in regions where irriga- tion has been heavily utilized, aquifers are exceeding replenishment rates (Nadal 2000: 7; see also Ackerman et al. 2003). As you will see in the following examples, many of these problems are surfacing in small communities such as San Juan Guelav´ıa as well. The Problem with Corn in San Juan Guelav´ıa: Environmental, Economic, and Social Challenges to Production The dilemma that arises from the loss of self-sufficiency in corn pro- duction in San Juan Guelav´ıa stems, in part, from the fact that corn is not merely a product but a way of life. Corn has nourished and organized the daily lives of community members as far back as any- one can remember.13 Despite its decline, Guelav´ıans still pride them- selves on their particular traditions of carefully selecting, cultivating, preparing, and consuming some of the best-tasting corn in Oaxaca. Situated on an arid valley floor in the eastern arm of the Valley of Oaxaca, generations of Guelav´ıans have depended on the saline river, el Rio Salado, that weaves through their milpa fields to give life to 12. Such as reducing or eliminating crop rotation and fallow periods, reducing labor-intensive soil and water conservation techniques, employing fertilizers and pes- ticides, intensifying water extraction, cultivating poorer quality soils, and the like. 13. According to townspeople and colonial documents collected in the national archives, San Juan Guelav´ıa was originally founded by maize farmers from the nearby village of Macuilx´ochitl at least as early as the sixteenth century, when it first appears in colonial documents under the name San Juan Quelaa (Ambrosio Guzm´an and Cruz Atayde 1999; De Aguilar 1994 [1777]; Garc´ıa Antonio 1999; Hern´andez 1984; Mendieta y N´un˜ez 1960; Taylor 1972). Browning, Mexican Agricultural Restructuring after NAFTA 91
  • 8. their crops when the annual rains flood its channel and disperse its waters as well as the salt. Nowadays, after more than ten years of drought, lush cornfields are more often jarringly juxtaposed to with- ered and brown ones or to abandoned fields left to grow wild. Even though Guelav´ıa once enjoyed a reputation for fertile alluvial soils and abundant corn fields, Lucio Mendieta y Nun˜ez (1960) documen- ted evidence of soil erosion and salinization as early as the 1950s. This situation has worsened with population growth over time, as well as with decades of depleted water resources and increased pres- sure on production. The only fields that continue to thrive inevitably display the distinctive log-support structures of wells. Even the pres- ence of wells, however, is no guarantee of a harvest. The collapse in production that peasant producers are facing is not due to their inefficiency as capitalists nor to cultural stubborn- ness, although some would assume that a reluctance to shift produc- tion to alternative crops indicates a general resistance to innovation among them. As I will elaborate, the problem with cultivating any crops in Guelav´ıa is that Guelav´ıans are experiencing a complicated constellation of ecological, economic, and social constraints on pro- duction. They lack sufficient water resources; they face rising costs and risks of production yet low prices; they face intense competition 92 Mexican Studies/Estudios Mexicanos
  • 9. for resources and markets; they lack access to credit or capital unless they receive income from off-farm economic activities; and, ironi- cally, they face labor shortages because of outmigration caused by the need to subsidize continued corn farming. Water Table Depletion: Rainfall, Microclimates, Wells, and Local Competition Located in the mountain highlands more than 5,500 feet above sea level in the Isthmus region of southern M´exico, Oaxaca’s weather patterns are heavily influenced by the mixture of pressure and tem- perature zones from the Pacific Ocean and the Gulf of M´exico, which creates what is known as the Mexican summer monsoon.14 The most critical precipitation period for farmers is the Can´ıcula, however, a period of midsummer drought that falls within the summer rains, a phenomenon that makes its strongest impact on M´exico’s southern region. More importantly, the Can´ıcula fluctuates in timing and dura- tion and, in recent years, has become less predictable, which greatly complicates farmers’ abilities to judge rainfall patterns. According to Don Faustino, a lifelong maize farmer, ‘‘[in Guelav´ıa] people say that the can´ıcula begins on June 16th . . . and leaves on August 24th. In the past, it used to rain more. The milpa could withstand the can´ıcula without extra water and you knew for sure that after the 24th of August, it was going to begin raining hard . . . But now we’re not even close to the 24th of August and the plants aren’t able to withstand it . . . Why? Because it no longer rains like it should.’’ In addition to unpredictable regional weather patterns, Oaxaca’s farmers are also affected by a myriad of microclimates as a result of immense topographic diversity. An important factor in local precip- itation is a phenomenon known as rain shadow effects from moun- tain ranges, especially if they are located to the northeast or southwest, which disrupts prevailing wind flows and hence rainfall. 14. Due to the proximity to the two coasts, precipitation patterns are also subject to annual fluctuations in El Nin˜o and La Nin˜a weather patterns (Dilley 1996; Magan˜a, et al. 2003).With a winter El Nin˜o, in which Pacific and Gulf of M´exico currents bring tropical storms and hurricanes to the coasts, the Valley experiences heavy rains, and, conversely, in a summer El Nin˜o, the Valley experiences drought (Magan˜a, et al. 2003). More particularly, El Nin˜o–Southern Oscillation (ENSO) warm current events have been associated with drought conditions in the Valley of Oaxaca as a result of a southward displacement of the Inter Tropical Convergence Zone (ITCZ), which re- duces tropical storms along the coasts (Dilley 1996; Magan˜a, et al. 2003). During La Nin˜a years, precipitation returns to normal or above average rainfall. Browning, Mexican Agricultural Restructuring after NAFTA 93
  • 10. As San Juan Guelav´ıa sits at the base of a mountain chain that runs along the southern edge of the eastern arm of the Valley, Guelav´ıans experience drought even when neighboring towns do not. As Don Faustino insisted, the can´ıcula takes its strongest effect ‘‘primarily in these towns [here], because from Tule and over there,’’ he pointed toward the towns to the west, ‘‘there it continues to rain. So, the can´ıcula is not even [‘‘no es pareja,’’ it is not balanced or fair].’’ Even among farmers who have installed wells, only very few are still able to grow corn because the underground water table has diminished. As Don Faustino explained, ‘‘Wells that should have a water mirror at six meters down at this time of year are now eight meters down . . . I had a well that measured six meters [earlier this season] and once I was ready to water the milpa, it didn’t respond. The aquifers have gone down more.’’15 As wells continue to dry, first on the agenda of every town-hall meeting (junta), and a topic of virtually every interview, was the corn harvest crisis. Not only were wells drying throughout the town and the fields, much of their re- maining water sources had become brackish. In addition to reduced rainfall, many Guelav´ıans blame receding water tables on the fact that the neighboring towns of Tlacocha- huaya16 and Tlacolula are both making heavy use of underground water sources in order to produce large volumes of chiles, tomatoes, and other produce for regional markets. This is considered particu- larly unjust because those crops require more water, and those other regions, despite their extremely close proximity, tend to receive more rain than Guelav´ıa. Curiously, from interviews and conversations with more than one hundred individuals, not a single person men- tioned the Benev´a mezcal factory recently built less than a kilometer from their agricultural lands. The large water demands of such opera- tions, however, likely place an additional burden on local water resources.17 15. Quotes taken from recorded interview with Don Faustino, August 10, 2007 (Code: R1_0127.10.2). 16. Tlacochahuaya is the main producer of chiles de agua (water chilies), named for their high water content. 17. In fact, the factory’s potential impact had not occurred to me either until I came across an online article criticizing Oaxaca’s governor for reportedly allowing the exploitation of vast amounts of water resources in several regions of the Valley to be dedicated to a new mezcal factory recently built under the label Zignum Mezcal. The factory produces mezcal primarily for export to Europe, Asia, and the United States. The distillery reportedly consumes great amounts of already depleted water resources from numerous farming communities in order to eventually produce 45,000 liters of mezcal daily. Although Benev´a may not be producing at quite this volume, it likely 94 Mexican Studies/Estudios Mexicanos
  • 11. Thus, Guelav´ıans are facing shortages not only of rainfall and underground aquifers, but also intense competition for water both within the community, with neighboring communities producing increasingly water-intensive crops, and quite possibly with the nearby mezcal factory. For the most part, only those farmers lucky enough to have plots close to the river or who have sufficient money to invest in concrete wells are among the diminishing number who continue to cultivate their fields fulltime. Migration and Low Prices Today, only a very small portion of Guelav´ıa’s population continues to support themselves primarily on corn cultivation. According to the national census (INEGI 2000), San Juan Guelav´ıa had 2,940 inhabi- tants, only 909 of whom were categorized as being of working age. Out of those, 898 were considered to be employed in some form of economic activity; of those employed, 446 received only minimum wage (approximately $50 pesos or US$5 per day) or less for their efforts, and another 257 were engaged in work for which they did not receive income, in other words, farmers without alternative sources of waged income. Virtually all residents must find additional income, and given the proportion of people earning at or below minimum wage, migration has become one of few options. Don Constantino, a lifelong maize farmer in his seventies, fre- quently reminisced about the old days when there had been so much rain that they often had to swim with baskets to reach their crops to harvest the fresh corn. These days, however, there is no such rain, no such harvest, and no such campesino (small farmer). ‘‘The young men of today,’’ he lamented, ‘‘they no longer know the sweat of the campo . . . Now no one works the land, because, for one thing, it no longer rains as it should, and, for another, the harvest no longer has the value like in the past. Right now, a lot of maize comes from who knows where, and they sell it for $2.5 pesos per kilo, and el criollo [locally ‘‘home-grown’’ maize] we need to sell for $3.5 pesos per kilo. Nobody wants to buy our criollo maize when so much is transported here, who knows from where. The little that I work, over there [on my fields], I have my mazorquita [little bit of corn], but who is going to buy it? And, who is going to use it also? Because, in the past when - places demands on local water resources. See the following online articles from The Narco News Bulletin (Davies 2010), e-consulta Oaxaca (Guerrero 2009) and Oax- acaLibre.org (Oaxaca Libre 2007). Browning, Mexican Agricultural Restructuring after NAFTA 95
  • 12. my wife was alive she made tortillas and tejate,18 but now, there is nobody to use the mazorca. Everything is bought now with money.’’ When I asked him if it was still possible to make a living growing corn, he flatly replied, ‘‘No. No, it is no longer possible to survive by selling corn alone even though one works very hard. The sellers [‘‘vendedores,’’ retailers] buy corn from other places, cheaper and cleaner . . . In the past, people would come [to my house] to buy 30 or 40 almudes.’’ An almud is equivalent to approximately 4 kilos of shucked corn. Since he sells an almud for $15 pesos (roughly $3.5 pesos per kilo), even 30 almudes represents $450 pesos (approxi- mately US$45), about half a month’s income based on the average daily wage in Oaxaca. ‘‘The families that still plant corn do other things to earn money,’’ he explained. ‘‘In the past, there was nothing else to dedicate oneself to but the fields. The true campesinos also harvested garbanzos, black beans, pumpkin seeds, and castor beans for making lamp oil. These things helped . . . Now everything arrives from the other side [from somewhere else] and none of those things help anymore.’’19 In Don Constantino’s explanation of what has happened to corn production, we hear that Guelav´ıan farmers are unable to compete with cheaper, preprocessed corn coming from commercial growers that is transported to the regional markets and even to the towns ‘‘from who knows where.’’ Guelavi´ans’ inability to compete with this cheaper corn is exacerbated by lack of rain, shifting labor, and changes in local preparation and consumption of traditional corn-based products. Yet, although Don Constantino says repeatedly that there is no maize in the fields and no campesinos growing it, as I eventually discovered, a ‘‘lack’’ of something for Guelav´ıans does not always mean its complete absence. Corn does still grow in Guelav´ıa, campesinos do still work their milpas, and women do still make tortillas and tejate. None of these practices are, however, per- formed at a level sufficient enough to sustain a way of life based on them. Given such production challenges, an important question to ask is why do some people continue to harvest corn and others do not (or cannot)? For those who continue to cultivate corn, how are they responding to the challenges of production and what are their options for meeting those challenges? What has been the outcome 18. Tejate is a traditional beverage made from a paste of primarily ground corn and chocolate. 19. Monograph compiled from recorded interview with Don Constantino, April 16, 2007 (Code: R1_0060.2.2) 96 Mexican Studies/Estudios Mexicanos
  • 13. for those who have shifted production practices or to other crops entirely? Land Distribution: The Dividing Lines of Corn Production in Guelav´ıa San Juan Guelav´ıa encompasses 17.86 Km2 of total land, which in- cludes saline or eroded lands unsuitable for cultivation, privately held agricultural lands, and 260 hectares (643 acres) of ejidal agricul- tural lands, which are divided into 503 parcels (INEGI 2007). Out of these, 44.6 percent (116 hectares/286 acres) are under cultivation; the remaining 55.4 percent are dedicated for other agricultural uses such as cattle grazing (INEGI 2007). Although ejidal lands are com- munally held plots, they are individually worked (INEGI 2007).20 Being a citizen of Guelav´ıa does not guarantee entitlement to an ejido plot, however. Although some families may have no ejidal lands, others may have multiple ejidal plots. Furthermore, although ejidal plots are roughly equal in size—ranging from about 0.5 to 1 hectare or about 1.25 to 2.5 acres—they can be extremely unequal in shape and quality, both in terms of soil and location, particularly regarding access to water. Regardless of size or quality of lands, ejidal plots are not large enough to support a family (Hall and Humphrey 2003: 16; Nadal 1999; 2000). Most ejidatarios have private lands as well. Based on data collected by Jeffrey Cohen from 2000 to 2004 (see Cohen and Browning 2007), approximately 80 percent of all Guelav´ıan families continued to farm, utilizing both rainfed and irrigation techniques on an average of 2.25 hectares (approximately 5.5 acres)—an amount well in excess of the average ejido plot size—and were able to pro- duce an average of about six to eight months worth of the maize needed for daily consumption.21 This indicates that at that time, 20. In anticipation of NAFTA, the Mexican government created a land certification program known as Programa de Certificaci´on de Derechos Ejidales y Titulaci´on de Solares Urbanos (PROCEDE). The program was meant to facilitate the process of privatizing communal lands and to unencumber land-titling procedures more gener- ally. This process has met with varying responses throughout M´exico. Nevertheless, Guelav´ıan ejido lands have been measured and certified, although not without con- tention. It remains unclear how certification will impact how Guelav´ıan lands will continue to be managed. 21. Based on Mexico’s national average rainfall, according to CEPAL (1982), at least 4 ha are necessary to produce enough corn for subsistence needs in this region without some form of irrigation. Therefore, many of Guelav´ıa’s producers would be considered sub-subsistence producers, and, indeed, most producers tend to diversify production strategies and household economic strategies to meet their daily needs. Browning, Mexican Agricultural Restructuring after NAFTA 97
  • 14. although most families were still continuing to harvest some corn, even eight years ago, they were not producing surpluses for sale in the market, and the large majority were well short of what they needed for their own subsistence despite farming on private as well as ejido lands. The extent of the situation was demonstrated to me while I was seated in an oddly oversized kitchen with Don Jerm´an, a lifelong maize farmer in his sixties. He said we were sitting in what had once been his grain room. With a dramatic wave of his hand Don Jerm´an explained, ‘‘This entire room [about 10 meters long by 4 meters wide by 4 meters high] used to be filled to the ceiling with maize at this time of year, and now,’’ he looked despairingly around the huge room and then pointed to a small pile of dried corn ears in the dark shadows of the furthest corner, ‘‘now there is nothing but that tiny pile over there.’’ He concluded that if no rain comes, ‘‘we will all soon have to abandon the fields.’’22 While most farmers reiterated Don Jerm´an’s complaints about failing corn harvests, they were in stark contrast to the comments of a minority of others, such as Don Rom´an who still had ample stores of maize in his solidly built multistory grain house, which was at least four times the size of Don Jerm´an’s former grain room. Don Rom´an insisted that one can still make a living growing maize, albeit with much more difficulty than in the past. An experienced maize farmer well into his late fifties, he attributed his good fortune to the fact that he had both tierra privada (privately owned land) and tierra ejidal and to his ability to work very hard.23 A bit perplexed, I questioned another town member about how Don Rom´an was able to generate such a good harvest when others were not. I was flatly told, with a disdainful snort, that his land was on the river, which meant he had the best soil and more water without the need for wells (which drastically reduced his labor and financial input) and could afford to hire a mozo (helper) to work the fields because of his good harvest and because he had sons in the United States sending money as well. I was told that approximately five families have such lands and such good harvests. The rest must buy at least some portion of their corn for the year. The stories of Don Jerm´an and Don Rom´an reveal growing differ- ences between the farmers who can continue to produce sufficient 22. Monograph compiled from recorded interview with Don Jerm´an, March 9, 2007 (Code: R1_0006.1.0). 23. Monograph compiled from recorded interview with Don Rom´an, April 12, 2007 (Code: R1_0043.1.1-2). 98 Mexican Studies/Estudios Mexicanos
  • 15. amounts of corn and those who cannot, which has to do not only with low prices and lack of rain, as Don Constantino told me earlier, but also with distribution of land, access to water, and access to migration networks. The patterns of faltering corn production closely match the patterns of land distribution and access to alternate forms of income to subsidize the rising costs and risks of production as well as diminishing returns. Thus, the differences between individual fam- ily resources, including not only physical resources but also social resources, profoundly impact the ability of Guelav´ıans to respond to the challenges in corn production they now face. In this sense, those who migrate are not necessarily leaving with the intent of abandon- ing production, but rather, in many cases, they are attempting to save it. For those who remain in Guelav´ıa and continue to harvest corn, even with remittance subsidies, production challenges are proving difficult to overcome. Rising Costs and Risks of Production Traditionally, farmers throughout this region have worked their lands with oxen and plow, relying only on rainfall and alluvial flooding to water their crops. With severe water shortages, fluctuating corn prices, and diminishing available family labor as a result of migration, however, most have had to modify these practices. In Guelav´ıa, those farmers who can afford to have been employing the use of tractors, in some cases making use of fertilizers, and installing deep wells along with a system of pumps and hoses. All of these more intensive farm- ing technologies place heavier demands on soil and water resources and are costly, even more so in such marginal and risky conditions. Unlike US farmers and Mexican commercial growers to the north, they have no insurance, no price supports, practically no subsidies, and no access to credit to help offset any of these costs and risks. Installing a well system can be particularly costly, and, as in the case of Don Faustino’s well, a well is no guarantee that reliable water will be obtained. Most farmers, like Don Faustino, dig until they reach water and then use a system of pumps and hard black plastic hoses. The cost of digging a dirt well varies depending on if help is hired and how deep the well must be dug. Pumps alone can cost around $5,000 pesos or US $500. Hose usually costs about $20 pesos per meter, and an average plot requires, at minimum, a couple hundred meters, amounting to another $4,000 pesos or more. Dirt wells, especially when they run deep, can collapse or run dry. The best chance of keeping water in a well is to install concrete rings, which can easily cost upward of $100,000 pesos, depending on the well depth. Given Browning, Mexican Agricultural Restructuring after NAFTA 99
  • 16. the high cost, only those who have access to migration remittances or other discretionary funds can afford to install them. Even for those who do manage to get a consistent water source, some are still unable to obtain a harvest because of outmigration and the lack of available help to cultivate fields. Exasperated, Don Faus- tino once complained that, despite water problems, faltering corn harvests are not just a result of lack of water because even when it does rain, few men are preparing their fields.24 Yet, many people, such as Don Faustino’s son who now lives in Ensenada, have left largely as a solution to lack of rain and low corn prices as well as to having few alternative sources of local income. Although they send money home to help augment family resources, converting those resources into production is hard if too few able hands are left to work the land. The Problem with Innovation: Efforts to Create New Opportunities in Guelav´ıa Thus far I have presented numerous obstacles to production; how- ever, some government subsidies have been made available for rural development, and numerous community members in San Juan Guelav´ıa are making use of such funds in an attempt to create new opportunities in the face of all these odds. Next I describe three examples of such efforts. All of these projects involved some use of state and/or federal funds and show how many people are attempting to cooperate with one another in a manner that is appropriate to capitalist forms of production. Yet, the mismatch of these efforts with community understandings of cooperation and competition gener- ates new tensions. In each case, we can see how engagement with government-funded projects foments conflict over resources and cre- ates particular roles for individuals who must coordinate and nego- tiate the use of funds provided and/or the management of projects and resources. Furthermore, government agricultural policies largely dictate the uses to which such funds are put. These policies may not take into consideration local needs nor the impact on local resources. The Potable Water Project In an effort to improve the availability and quality of water for home consumption, the municipio (town council) undertook to build 24. Based on recorded interview with Don Faustino, March 9, 2007 (Code: R1_ 0003-5.1.1-3). 100 Mexican Studies/Estudios Mexicanos
  • 17. a public water system with a combination of municipal and state funds. The system is based on a deep well that fills a large storage tank where the water is sanitized. Access is available to all residents, provided they can pay to install the piping to connect to the main line, a tank for home storage, a water meter, and pay for their monthly usage. Each of the three sections of the town receives water for two days out of each week. During the two-day period of water flow, use is restricted only by an individual’s capacity to store it and ability to pay for it. The municipal water committee, a subcommittee appointed by the cabildo, controls access to the main line by requir- ing a permit. Although the permit is free, many say that some com- mittee members charge unofficial ‘‘fees’’ for the water actually to get to a resident’s home or land. Although the potable water project was greatly needed, as many had been forced to buy water from water trucks during the increas- ingly protracted dry seasons, many residents also complained that the new system was depleting the water table and blamed it for wells drying up throughout the town. On one hand, these criticisms were lodged against the current presidente and his cabildo administration, who were a constant focus of critique and reflected a very real con- cern about the possibility of unsustainable water-table depletion and the fact that no real measures were being put in place to monitor excessive usage. On the other hand, these complaints were also about a new form of community water management that threatened what little equita- ble access to community resources might have remained. Since water had been considered a community resource available to everyone, the idea that they had to pay for such a resource, that people could take what water they want as long as they could pay for it, and that a community resource was being controlled by a few people who potentially stood to gain from their positions, caused many to be skeptical about the implementation and/or management of the pro- ject. For some, the water project was a step toward greater progress, something that marked them as a modern community; for others, it provided a badly needed necessity; and for others, it was a necessary evil. For the latter group, while the system provided more greatly needed water, it was also a form of attack on communally shared resources, locking them into expenses for which they must struggle to find money. Although compatible with a capitalist notion of devel- opment, one in which access to resources is linked to one’s ability to acquire them and fairness is ideally regulated by effort—anyone can access as much water as he or she wants so long as that person puts forward the initiative to obtain money—the imperative to compete Browning, Mexican Agricultural Restructuring after NAFTA 101
  • 18. sets individuals at odds with one another as they have unequal abil- ities to do so. Such an orientation is incompatible with notions of equal entitlement to resources. That said, the large majority did admit that the potable water project was an improvement for the town and helped meet the needs of people who have little or no water. Some, who both have milpa plots close enough to the main line and have the funds necessary, have been able to use the water for their crops. Others, such as Don Roberto, told me they would have liked to make use of the new water for crops but had been unable to take advantage of it for lack of available capital or for lack of available help in the fields. In Don Roberto’s case, because he had several sons living in the United States sending money home, he had enough saved—approximately $100,000 pesos—to restart his ‘‘alfalfa and corn business’’ by tapping into the new water source. He felt he could make ‘‘a good living’’ farming multiple plots—except that, because his sons were in the United States, he had no help in the fields. Alianza para el Campo y Caja por Caja One of numerous government funded programs administered through Alianza para el Campo (Alliance for the Countryside)25 to provide economic assistance to poor rural communities and to subsidize livestock production is Caja por Caja (Crate for Crate). Through this program, qualifying individuals receive a crate of animals—usually chickens, turkeys, or pigs—in exchange for an equivalent crate of animals at a later date. The government pays for half the expense of the original purchase price of the animals, and the individuals are allowed to raise and breed, sell, or consume the off- spring. Then on a prespecified date, they return the same number of animals of equivalent quality, size, and age that they originally received. Although simple in concept, as Don Faustino explained, utilizing the program turns out to be a bit more complicated than it sounds. A few years earlier, when Don Faustino held a post on the ejido committee, he worked with this program, which he referred to as ‘‘modalidad dos’’ (second tier). This was how he referred to Alianza’s 25. Since this study was conducted, the name for Alianza para el Campo has been changed to Activos Productivos. For the purposes of this paper, however, the name of the program utilized at the time of the study is preserved. For a concise explaination of Alianza para el Campo, the benefits it offers, and who does or does not receive them, see Brian Palmer-Rubin 2010. 102 Mexican Studies/Estudios Mexicanos
  • 19. modalidad PADER. Alianza provides subsidies under two different tiers (SAGARPA-SIAP 2009).26 The first, modalidad normal (normal tier), generally provides a smaller proportion of funds, usually 20 to 25 percent of proposed project costs, for rural development (for example, soils improvements, tractor purchases, greenhouse con- struction, and the like) to a wider base of beneficiaries. Modalidad PADER, the second tier, provides a higher proportion of benefits, usually up to 50 percent of costs but is limited only to those who qualify under PADER standards.27 Usually Alianza provides funds to those producers who are trying to develop or augment agricultural and livestock products that it wishes to promote. Those who wish to secure such aid, regardless of the tier, must apply through SAGARPA. Because the application process and providing correct documentation are often the barriers for inhabitants of poorer communities, numerous individuals ap- proached Don Faustino to help them secure funds from the caja por caja program. Unclear about how the process of procuring the funds and livestock actually works, I asked him how such details are kept track of. Does someone have a list of the size, weight, and descrip- tions of the animals? Does that person oversee the delivery and return of livestock? And how would one go about making the arrangements for this exchange? Don Faustino did not seem at all surprised by my dismay. As he laughed at the tediousness of the idea, he explained, ‘‘Yes, well . . . for example, if I want to get some chickens, I go down to the government office [SAGARPA] and they tell me I first need to get three bids on prices for chickens and then I’ll need to submit an application. So, I go to some dealers and they each give me a quote. And perhaps I also ask a few friends or a few women in town, people who know chickens well, to see what they think of the price. ‘Does the price suit you or not?’ If it does, then, alright, we’ll go make the contract. And then we go down to the government office, and there I submit an application with the credentials of all the people who want to purchase the chickens along with the credentials of the three dealers and their 26. See the SAGARPA-SIAP website for current and past Reglas de operaci´on de la Alianza para el Campo (Rules of Operation for Alliance for the Countryside), includ- ing a description of how benefits are distributed and specific requirements for quali- fications of beneficiaries (SAGARPA-SIAP 2009). 27. PADER refers to the standards of qualifications for the Programa de De- sarrollo Rural (Program for Rural Development), which determines the level of under investment and marginalization of rural communities. Those communities with very low investment and high levels of marginalization meet the PADER standards, which qualifies them for increased subsidies for rural development and upliftment. Browning, Mexican Agricultural Restructuring after NAFTA 103
  • 20. price quotes. And then that’s it, but it takes a long time, six months or a year will pass. And, well, if they authorize us, great, or if something is lacking they don’t authorize us, for some trouble with the require- ments, or . . . well, they make a study to see if the project is good or not. Many times they authorize us but many times they do not. For all the pueblos this happens.’’ Don Faustino went on to describe an example, among many others, in which he had helped procure some pigs. ‘‘With pigs, they say a caja is ten female pigs and one male, so a caja is eleven pigs let’s say. We had arranged for a caja of full-grown pigs, for which one has to give some $1,500 pesos each, even though they actually cost $3,000 pesos each . . . The price depends on the type of pig.’’ With a chuckle he added, ‘‘And you see, here, we know types of pigs like you know types of cars. There are different qualities of each . . . So, the government gave us the permission. But then, six months passed and I hadn’t yet made a decision, as the representative of the people who wanted the pigs, but that was because the pigs that were approved were very expensive for them. Each person would have had to pay $1,000 pesos for each pig, because they were high quality pigs, but, for the people it didn’t suit them for lack of money . . . I decided to go to the dealer and explained that the people could not afford these pigs but the price the government had settled on was already fixed . . . So, he said he would give us thirty lower quality piglets for the price of the eleven high-quality adult ones . . . This was much better for the people because each pig would cost around $200 pesos, so each person would give $100 pesos and the government would give $100 pesos. Very good . . . So, the dealer made the receipt for a caja of pigs and we agreed that there were thirty small pigs . . . and in this way more people benefitted, no?’’ After the dealers receive their payment in full, a delivery date must then be arranged. Once set by the dealer, the town representa- tive must go in person to the government office to notify them of the date. Then a representative from SAGARPA will come on the same day at the same time to inspect the delivery and the recipients. And then all the people who are to receive the delivery must also be advised in person to be there at the same time so, as Don Faustino explained, ‘‘the SAGARPA official can note down what each person received, note their identification documents, to know who they all are, where they live, each one has this particular animal and so on. They take photos, collect all the requirements, and finally all is done. Except that if it is a caja por caja arrangement, the representative must later come on the day that is set to collect the caja that is owed in return, perhaps in six months or, if they are lucky, a year.’’ 104 Mexican Studies/Estudios Mexicanos
  • 21. Shrugging, he surmised, ‘‘So you see, it is like that. And as the representative, well, it is a matter of losing time, to go and ask, and to see the items, to get different prices, to make the negotiations, to submit the applications, to wait for the approval, to organize all the people, back and forth and back and forth. And, well, I lose these things [all this time], but it is in order to obtain something for them, for the people. Good, ok. This is one of the satisfactions of being a leader, you know, that one feels in representing the people. But that’s all, no more. Because some people that don’t understand, they think that someone would take something, that they would make some earning out of it but no,’’ he tisked in annoyance, ‘‘no, it is not like that.’’ That people had accused him of taking advantage of his position to gain from these transactions seemed particularly absurd to him, given that it would not have even been worth the effort to take advantage when the gains were so little and the efforts were so great.28 What we hear from Don Faustino, then, is that while the govern- ment makes available some aid to small farmers, given the high degree of undercapitalization in these communities, even paying half the costs for animals is often too high an investment for cash-poor individuals. For people who have access to more cash and particu- larly those who are also knowledgeable about such programs, how- ever, the potential for increasing their gains is much higher. Clearly, the gains to be made through purchasing some $20 peso chickens or $200 peso pigs are quite small, and yet the efforts to obtain them substantial. In contrast, if one were to invest $1,000 pesos, the effort is the same but the returns far greater. More importantly though, all of these gains, no matter how small or big, are fundamentally con- tingent on one’s ability to access these benefits successfully. I would like to emphasize here that although the process of applying for such funds seems nonsensical in its over complication, many such requirements have been implemented to ensure that ben- efits reach the people for whom they were intended. All of the exces- sive receipting, documenting, and identifying of animals and people were at least presumably put in place to prevent abuses. The real irony is that potential abusers can still easily find a way around such procedures, for example, through bribery or through getting various people to apply for funds on their behalf, whereas the intended beneficiaries are the ones who ultimately pay the consequences because the application procedures themselves can become the main 28. Details and quotes in this section compiled from recorded interview with Don Faustino, April 26, 2007 (Code: R1_0066.4.1). Browning, Mexican Agricultural Restructuring after NAFTA 105
  • 22. barrier to receiving such funds. Even for those who are knowledge- able about applying for such funds and who have the literacy skills to do so, often just the time and expense of acquiring identification documents such as proper birth records can cost more in terms of money and effort than they stand to gain from the subsidies. I would actually identify lack of documents or lack of correctly and consis- tently filled-out documents as a crucial obstacle to restructuring pro- duction efforts, an important issue I take up in greater detail elsewhere (Browning 2009). In Don Faustino’s case, he was knowledgeable enough about working with the government bureaucracy to know the process of preparing and submitting applications and had all the proper docu- mentation, but still, there was no guarantee that such funds would be received. Much time and effort can be spent only to have the appli- cation be mysteriously denied. Nevertheless, by virtue of necessitat- ing a negotiator to carry out the transactions, many in the community suspected that such programs further enabled certain people with more knowledge and good positioning to gain personally from their roles. Setting aside the potential pettiness of Don Faustino’s critici- zers, that someone in his position would try to benefit from his or her situation is entirely plausible. As we will see in the final example, such suspicions impact cooperation within group projects as well. Two Greenhouses, a Bunch of Tomatoes, and a Dead Dog During a municipal junta in the Spring of 2007,29 numerous outspo- ken townspeople complained about the preferential help they believed had been given to an invernadero (greenhouse) project for growing tomatoes undertaken by Don Faustino and funded through both the municipal government and Alianza’s Modalidad PADER pro- gram. Many were upset that the municipio would provide funds and allow community resources to be used for what was essentially a pri- vate project. The presidente quickly responded to these complaints by assuring residents that these benefits were open to anyone in the community. The government, he explained, will help pay for the costs of projects by individuals or groups in the town who plan to produce certain kinds of crops as set forth by Alianza regulations. He called on all those in attendance to come to the municipio with their ideas so that they could help them to prepare proposals for funding as well. The crowd openly scoffed at his offer, both in disbelief that 29. Junta details compiled from recorded meeting and fieldnotes, April 13, 2007 (Code: R1_0055.1; FN-G-10.4.13). 106 Mexican Studies/Estudios Mexicanos
  • 23. help would materialize and in recognition of the difficulty of coming up with a viable project. It seemed particularly absurd to them that the government and the municipio would help with such expensive and water-intensive projects as greenhouse tomatoes but would not help salvage their most essential crop: corn. They felt that developing the deep wells and irrigation that would restore corn crops would surely require less water than tomatoes. Besides, how many green- houses could one town support? Residents did not view this approach as part of a strategy that would benefit all community mem- bers; rather, it would help only those who had sufficient resources and connections. Furthermore, several individuals hotly expressed their concern about the extensive water demands of growing large volumes of tomatoes, which would no doubt further deplete the community’s aquifers. The cabildo justified the use of community resources, how- ever, because these were the choices the government offered and because it would provide the community with a locally grown, less- expensive, and reliable source of tomatoes at the same time that it would potentially help develop a local industry. As Don Faustino explained to me, ‘‘The idea was that it could be an example, a test, to see if we could come up with some kind of secure work, to see if others in the community should enter into this kind of project, you know, if the greenhouse turned out to be viable.’’ He even referred to the project as a commitment between their group, the government, and the community. Somewhat irritated with community members’ responses to the proposal, he complained, ‘‘Most people just don’t seem to understand that they too can receive this kind of funding.’’ In fact, two greenhouse projects for growing tomatoes had actu- ally been initiated by community members and undertaken with sub- sidies from state government and municipio funds. The two projects were submitted to SAGARPA through the municipio at more or less the same time in 2005. After about ten months’ time, both projects were eventually approved, given that they were the only two projects that had been submitted for government funding from San Juan Guelav´ıa. Although both greenhouse projects were ultimately funded and built in 2006, they had very different outcomes. These outcomes were due, in part, to the way in which the greenhouses were managed, as one was essentially undertaken by one individual, Don˜a Lila, whereas the other was undertaken by a group of ten individuals, including Don Faustino and an agronomist from outside San Juan Guelav´ıa. After some disagreements among members, their group was later reduced to seven members, six men and one woman. Browning, Mexican Agricultural Restructuring after NAFTA 107
  • 24. After assessing the cost of construction for a 300 meter2 green- house, the state and federal government approved a total cost of $290,000 pesos (US $29,000) to build each greenhouse, with half of the costs being paid by the government and the remaining $145,000 pesos being paid, in part, by the municipal government and, in part, by the individual beneficiaries of each of the projects. As Don˜a Lila already had the money in place for her share of her project, a little more than $70,000 pesos after the municipio invested its portion, her greenhouse was erected first. In the meantime, Don Faustino’s group, whose members were struggling to come up with their share of the funds, shopped around for other greenhouse prices. Although they were required to match the $145,000 peso amount set by the government, they found a company that would construct a green- house of considerably larger size, some 500 meters2 , for the same price but using more economical materials. This increase could almost double their potential returns. After municipal funds were contributed, each partner in Don Faustino’s group had to invest approximately $10,000 pesos (US $1,000) for the greenhouse construction. Based on advice from a horticultural and soils engineer, they selected a variety of hybrid tomato plants that generate very high yields but are also susceptible to fungi as well as pests. For this rea- son, both greenhouses required a fairly complex system of double entry doors and a sanitation room in order to prevent the introduc- tion of diseases or pests that could induce crop failures. Although Don Faustino’s group managed to make it through their first growing season without such catastrophe, Don˜a Lila was not so lucky. Accord- ing to several community members, her greenhouse suffered large losses due to contamination. Many speculated this was because she hired laborers who were not as careful as Don Faustino’s group, whose members did all the work themselves. Some people even suspected his group of having sabotaged Don˜a Lila’s project. Accord- ing to Don Faustino and his partners, however, one of the advantages of the company that constructed their greenhouse was that it also provided the plants and offered a guarantee of not only the structure and water systems, but also the plants. For this reason, they period- ically sent technicians to inspect the structure and the harvests to help ensure that the crop was successful. Clearly, this played an important role in the eventual success of their project relative to the unfortunate outcome of Don˜a Lila’s. Nevertheless, Don Faustino’s group did not make it through the year unscathed. Many differences had arisen within the group. There were disagreements over who should control the keys to the facilities 108 Mexican Studies/Estudios Mexicanos
  • 25. and over deciding how resources and labor were to be divided. As Don Faustino explained, ‘‘One person wanted more order but then wouldn’t arrive at the time designated. Another, a soils engineer from outside, criticized the work but didn’t do any of the work himself. Another didn’t work but always showed up and another didn’t come at the designated times but worked on his own. And so on.’’30 Although the original agreement among the members was that each partner would receive an equal share of the tomatoes at harvest, which they were then entitled to sell as they saw fit, many felt the input from members had not been equal. Resentment grew among members over the course of the season about the unequal share of work performed, and some questioned whether those who had put in less effort should receive the same share of tomatoes as those who had put in considerably more effort. One member in particular had consistently failed to complete his share of the work. After several aggravating months, once the harvests were ready, the group informed him that he would be given a smaller portion of the tomatoes, which they had already set aside for him after having taken their own shares. Following a particularly heated argument, he left with his tomatoes in a fit of anger, swearing he would have nothing more to do with the project. A few days later, the water pump for the irrigation system became clogged. After a short investigation, an already putrefied dead dog was discovered in the greenhouse well. Since the well was tightly covered, the group was adamant that it could not have been an accident. Although no one implicated the particular disgruntled individual, everyone clearly suspected him of the misdeed. With all the widespread complaints about water use for the greenhouse and the accusations of sabotaging Don˜a Lila’s greenhouse, however, no one could be certain of the culprit. Given that a water-source contamination such as a dead dog presented a serious health problem, the well, the tank, and the entire hose system had to be purged and disinfected, which required that someone descend into the well to remove the carcass and clean the well. The disgust with which Don Faustino described this task made clear that it had been a difficult situation that left many members of the group sore. Exasperated with the difficulty of achieving cooper- ation and the desperate lengths to which people went to undermine one another, he shook his head, raising his hands in a helpless ges- ture of resignation, ‘‘How are we going to resolve something like this?’’ 30. Excerpt from recorded interview with Don Faustino, April 26, 2007 (Code: R1_0067-4.1). Browning, Mexican Agricultural Restructuring after NAFTA 109
  • 26. Despite such setbacks, the greenhouse eventually produced a good crop. By the spring of 2006, the first tomato plants had been transplanted and by June they began harvesting. Over the three- month harvest season, the greenhouse churned out almost three tons of tomatoes, which sold for approximately $15 to $20 pesos per kilo. As the group was entitled to keep all of the earnings, they managed to receive a fair return on their investment: they had to invest a com- bined total of $70,000 pesos to erect the greenhouse and then had to purchase plants, fertilizers, and pesticides, for which they received some modest subsidies. Then they put in their labor. They received a gross return of between $90,000 and $120,000 pesos.31 As the group felt the endeavor was profitable, they continued planting the following year. By mid-summer of 2007, I spoke with Don Faustino after he had finished tallying up the production for the second season thus far. ‘‘We’re already at three tons and we’re only just reaching halfway through the harvest season,’’ he proudly smiled. He nodded at my surprise with satisfaction. ‘‘But there is a difference—’’ he paused for effect, ‘‘the price,’’ he finally said flatly. ‘‘Last year we sold at $15 to $20 pesos per kilo, and now,’’ he again paused for effect, ‘‘now we’re selling at $7 pesos per kilo.’’ They were producing double yet selling for less than half the price. ‘‘Why? What happened?’’ I asked him. ‘‘Well, you see, it’s that now there’s already many others who are doing this [growing tomatoes] and there are many that have green- houses. Practically every pueblo has at least one. And then, there is so much that arrives here from other places. In other words, there is competition.’’32 The Problem with Good Intentions In all of the examples provided, especially in the case of the two greenhouses, we can surmise that the problem with good intentions when it comes to agricultural restructuring is that they have many unintended consequences. Although government funds have been made available to subsidize the development of horticultural crops and livestock products that were identified and targeted in the NAFTA 31. As the price fluctuated within the season, between $15 and $20 pesos per kilo, this range is calculated based on the selling price and volume produced that Don Faustino provided. He did not tell me a specific number for the gross profit. I’m not sure they even know an exact gross amount since most of these transactions were carried out in cash by each individual separately. 32. Excerpt from recorded interview with Don Faustino, July 5, 2007 (Code: R1_ 0105.9.1). 110 Mexican Studies/Estudios Mexicanos
  • 27. agreements to replace faltering corn harvests and aid rural liveli- hoods, the manner in which these programs have been implemented has had many unfortunate consequences at the community level. First, many people neither understand how the government pro- grams work nor how to access them. This misunderstanding creates the sense that those who apply for and receive such funds have done so through illegitimate means. They are suspected of either receiving advantages by way of favoritism, by way of their position or financial means, or simply by way of knowing more than others. The erratic way in which the government approves or denies proposals—which often has to do with filling quotas for a particular region or other such bureaucratic considerations—contributes to the perception that some people get more ‘‘favors’’ through either position or outright bribery. The variable outcomes of such projects, such as the contam- ination in Don˜a Lila’s greenhouse versus the lack of contamination in Don Faustino’s, is again evidence for many of ill-doings in order to get ahead and yet, at the same time, results from uneven distribution of information and knowledge. Don Faustino’s group, comprised of several individuals who were knowledgeable about working with other government-funded projects, managed to seek out a more secure arrangement for their project than did Don˜a Lila. Despite their knowledge of working with such programs and their experience as farmers, however, these examples demonstrate the great degree of risk that individuals must undertake in order to shift to new crops and technologies. This risk is part of the reason why many individuals, even those who have the resources to under- take such a project, still prefer to stick with what they know: corn. Although returns might be low, they stand a better chance of staying afloat by investing in increased corn production, albeit perhaps on more marginal land and/or utilizing more marginal production prac- tices. Furthermore, given corn’s long shelf life and its centrality to the American diet, farmers can consume what they produce. In contrast, the quick deterioration of tomatoes makes their cultivation more risky and their markets more volatile. Second, work within Don Faustino’s greenhouse group was extremely difficult to negotiate. Cooperation among partners was tenuous at best, in large part because each member had equal say in the management of the project and yet no authority to demand anything of the others. The only way in which they could enforce control over others was to band together as a group and deny another a portion of his or her share. As we have seen, however, this action may have had dramatic consequences. As Don Faustino once told me, ‘‘People here would prefer to have several quiet enemies than one Browning, Mexican Agricultural Restructuring after NAFTA 111
  • 28. loud one’’ or, as it turned out, a dead dog in the well. For someone like Don Faustino, the application procedures for applying for gov- ernment funds feel like less of a barrier to getting ahead than do his own people. Much like George Foster (1967) and Eric Wolf (1957) long ago argued about closed-corporate communities, great effort must be exerted to avoid provoking the dangerous consequences of anger and envy (see also, for example, Greenberg 1989; Kearney 1972; Nader 1964; and Nash 1967). Yet such communities are not closed. Differences in wealth are increasing rather than being leveled while community members still attempt to regulate the community using standards of communally shared resources, which are not nec- essarily compatible with engagement in private enterprise when they involve the use of extremely limited community resources. When it takes place within the parameters of capitalist production, coopera- tion in such projects feels less like cooperation for the good of the community and more like individual profiteering utilizing the bene- fits of ‘‘free’’ community resources. Third, in the second year of production, as Don Faustino’s toma- toes were ripening on the vines, the regional price in tomatoes fell because there had been so much competition in the market for toma- toes. Although the Mexican government has been promoting the shift to such horticultural crops through its subsidy programs for campe- sinos, it has been doing so across the board. Now the glut of tomatoes produced in the northern states for urban domestic consumption and export to the north is making its way to the south; at the same time, locally, practically every town has put in a greenhouse to grow tomatoes because it is one of the few things for which they can receive some sort of investment help. And, unlike corn, tomatoes cannot be stored until a time when the prices might be more favor- able. Although Don Faustino’s group did still make a profit the sec- ond year, this was only because they had a much larger harvest than the first year. For group members, the endeavor was difficult, and given the price fluctuations of tomatoes, they said they were consid- ering perhaps growing a different product next time, although no one was quite sure exactly what. Finally, the crops such farmers can grow if they wish to transition away from corn are largely determined by what the government will help fund. Yet, the government seems to have given little forethought in the new agricultural plan for M´exico regarding the viability and sustainability of the crops they have chosen to promote. The focus on horticultural crops as directed by the terms of NAFTA seems particu- larly perverted as those crops tend to be so water intensive and are going to be grown in known drought-prone regions. This poses 112 Mexican Studies/Estudios Mexicanos
  • 29. particular challenges to local resource management, particularly because the promotion of such crops has been indiscriminate. The only way to make up for low prices as these crops reach saturation point is to produce more of them, demanding even more water re- sources and further deflating prices because there are virtually no other alternatives. Plowing Ahead: Directions for Future Research and Development Through the course of this paper, I have shown how corn producers in San Juan Guelav´ıa face numerous challenges that could be catego- rized as environmental, economic, social, and political. I have also shown the ways they have been responding to these challenges. In some cases, they have attempted to increase production when they had the ability to do so, generally determined by their access to water, good land, help, and to off-farm resources such as migration remit- tances. Such investment has proven extremely risky, however, in the context of drought, competition for scarce resources, and low crop prices. In other cases, producers have augmented or abandoned corn production by shifting to new production strategies and crops such as the greenhouse projects, although lack of government support in regulating and stabilizing markets, even for the crops they are pro- moting to producers, undermines their production efforts and en- courages increased consumption for scarce water resources. In yet other cases, farmers have left Guelav´ıa entirely, sometimes to build a life elsewhere but often to subsidize production for those family members who have remained at home. As I stated at the opening of this article, while the picture is bleak for Guelav´ıan producers, it is not entirely without hope. Were more concerted effort put into researching and funding crops that can be sustainably harvested in drought-prone regions, concomitant with government commitment to regulate, stabilize, and enhance small- farmer access to markets for their goods, Guelav´ıans could stand a chance of rebuilding lives and livelihoods. Investigating the viability of deep wells, reservoirs, and irrigation systems could potentially help restabilize production if water conservation were also more closely promoted and regulated. Furthermore, the general paucity of capital in these regions is a primary barrier to restructuring pro- duction efforts. Even according to the World Bank, the cost of doing business in southern M´exico is much higher than anywhere else in the country, and this is particularly true for small entrepreneurs and family farms due to ‘‘the scarcity and poor quality of financial services Browning, Mexican Agricultural Restructuring after NAFTA 113
  • 30. in the region,’’ which has the lowest bank density in the nation (Caballero 2003: 13–14). In the World Bank’s findings, only 15 per- cent of Banca Popular institutions and 5 percent of Mexican com- mercial banks even operate in the south. Worse, the majority of money deposited into southern banks tends to be lent out of state, most often to the federal government for bonds, rather than being reinvested in the capital-poor farms and small business enterprises trying to make a living in the south (see also Gordillo de Anda, et al. 1999: 117–131; Myhre 1996: 117–138; 1998: 39–65). Investigating and developing the potential of micro-banking or simply making available affordable rural credit could do much to help rural peoples regain some level of self-sufficiency. Although some subsidies and other funding have been made available to small farmers, as I have shown, often the knowledge of such programs and the process of accessing their benefits are formidable barriers to utilizing them. Promoting programs in a manner appropriate to regions of high illiteracy and simplifying the complicated nature of applying for them is yet another key area of improvement. Finally, any efforts that are made to investigate and improve rural livelihoods should take into account local needs and understanding; otherwise, they are likely to fail. One could argue that rural programs such as Alianza para el Campo were never really intended to work; rather, such programs were put in place to placate the poor rural masses with empty promises and programs. The way in which they have been implemented, however, not only fails to capitalize produc- tion, but also undermines the social systems and the resource base of the communities they were intended to help. Since such programs are already in place, why not start by making them more effective? Restoring sustainable rural self-sufficiency to the hands that have long fed the nation is not simply a matter of good will—I argue it is in the national self interest. Doing so could help curb the flow of migrants to the ever-expanding high-risk populations of urban poor and will help secure the water and food security of the nation for future generations. References Ackerman, Frank, Timothy A. Wise, Kevin P. Gallagher, Luke Ney, and Regina Flores. 2003. ‘‘Free Trade, Corn, and the Environment: Environmental Impacts of US – Mexico Corn Trade under NAFTA.’’ Working Paper No. 03-06: Global Development and Environment Institute, Tufts University. http://are.berkeley.edu/courses/EEP131/old_files/ AckermanCorn.pdf. 114 Mexican Studies/Estudios Mexicanos
  • 31. Ambrosio Guzm´an, Liliana V., and Marytza Cruz Atayde. 1999. San Juan Guelav´ıa: Plan municipal de desarrollo. Thesis, Ciencias en Planificaci´on de Empresas y Desarrollo Regional. Oaxaca, M´exico: Instituto Tecnol´ogico de Oaxaca. Appendini, Kirsten. 2001. De la milpa a los tortibonos:la restructuraci´on dela pol´ıticaalimentariaenM´exico.M´exico:ElColegiodeM´exico,Institutode Investigaci´ones de las Naciones Unidas para el Desarollo Social. Arrellanes Meixueiro, Anselmo. 2004. Conflictos por comunales en el Sur de M´exico. Presented at ‘‘The Commons in an Age of Global Transition: Challenges, Risks and Opportunities,’’ the 10th annual conference of the IASCP, August 9–13. Oaxaca, Oaxaca: International Association for the Study of Common Property (IASC). www.iascp2004.org.mx (accessed March 10, 2005). ASERCA. 2009. Database: Apoyos y Servicios a la Comercializaci´on Agropecuaria (ASERCA). www.aserca.gob.mx. Audley, John, Demetrios G. Papademetriou, Sandra Polaski, and Scott Vaughan. 2004. NAFTA’s Promise and Reality: Lessons from Mexico for the Hemisphere. Washington, D.C.: Carnegie Endowment for International Peace. Browning, Anjali. 2009. South of Hope: The Impacts of US - Mexican Restructuring and Faltering Corn Production on the Lives of Indigenous Zapotec Maize Farmers in Oaxaca, Mexico. Doctoral dissertation, Department of Anthropology. University of California, Los Angeles. Bryceson, Deborah Fahy. 2002. ‘‘The Scramble in Africa: Reorienting Rural Livelihoods.’’ World Development 30: 725–739. Caballero, Jos´e Mar´ıa. 2003. ‘‘Agriculture and Rural Development.’’ In Gill Hall and Christopher Humphrey (eds.), Mexico Southern States Development Strategy, Volume 1. Online Report: The World Bank. http://documents.worldbank.org/curated/en/2003/10/5531347/mexico- southern-states-development-strategy CEPAL. 1982. Econom´ıa campesina y agricultura empresarial: tipolog´ıa de productores del agro Mexicano, M´exico: Siglo XXI. Mexico. Cohen, Jeffrey H. 2004a. ‘‘Community, Economy and Social Change in Oaxaca, Mexico: Rural Life and Cooperative Logic in the Global Economy.’’ In Gerardo Otero (ed.), Mexico in Transition: Neoliberal Globalism, The State and Civil Society (Globalization and the Semi- Periphery: Impacts, Opposition, Alternatives), 154–168. London and New York: Zed Books. ———. 2004b. The Culture of Migration in Southern Mexico. Austin: University of Texas Press. Cohen, Jeffrey H., and Anjali Browning. 2007. ‘‘The Decline of a Craft: Basket MakinginSan JuanGuelav´ıa,Oaxaca.’’ Human Organization 66: 229–239. Cornelius, Wayne A., and David Myhre (eds.). 1998. The Transformation of Rural Mexico: Reforming the Ejido Sector. La Jolla: Center for U.S.- Mexican Studies, University of California, San Diego. Davies, Nancy. 2010. ‘‘Coca-Cola Moves into Mezcal: Agro-Industry Absorbs Oaxaca Land and Water for Private Profit, Stainless Steel Vats Replace Browning, Mexican Agricultural Restructuring after NAFTA 115
  • 32. Artisanship.’’ The Narco News Bulletin. www.narconews.com/Issue64/ article4045.html (accessed February 27, 2010). De Aguilar, Fr. Augustin. 1994 [1777]. ‘‘San Juan Teitipac, Tlacolula: Ms. 2450, (No. 92), ff. 199–200v.’’ In Manuel Esparza (ed.), Relaciones geogr´aficas de Oaxaca: 1777–1778, 309–313. Oaxaca, M´exico: Centro de Investigaciones y Estudios Superiores en Antropolog´ıa Social (CIESAS), Instituto Oaxaquen˜o de las Culturas. De Janvry, Alain, Elisabeth Sadoulet, and Jerm´an Gordillo de Anda. 1995. ‘‘NAFTA and Mexico’s Maize Producers.’’ World Development 23: 1349–1362. Dilley, Maxx. 1996. ‘‘Synoptic Controls on Precipitation in the Valley of Oaxaca, Mexico.’’ International Journal of Climatology 16: 1019–1031. Emanuel, Robert M., and James B. Greenberg. 2000. ‘‘Lluvia Enojada–Tyoo Kuasi’: The Political Ecology of Forest Extraction in the Sierra Chatina, Oaxaca.’’ Journal of Political Ecology 7: 43–63. FAO. 2007. ‘‘FAO Statistical Yearbook 2005–2006, Vol. I.’’ Web Edition: FAO Statistics Division. www.fao.org/statistics/yearbook (accessed January 16, 2009). FAOSTAT. 2009. FAO Statistics Division, Database: Food and Agriculture Organization of the United Nations (FAO). www.faostat.fao.org (accessed February 16, 2009). Feiss, Norbert, and Daniel Lederman. 2004. ‘‘Mexican Corn: The Effects of NAFTA,’’ Trade Note 18, Document No. 32109. Washington, D.C.: International Trade Department, The World Bank. Foster, George McClelland. 1967. ‘‘Peasant Society and the Image of Limited Good.’’ In Jack M.Potter,MayN.Diaz, andGeorge McClelland Foster (eds.), Peasant Society: A Reader, 300–323. Boston: Little, Brown and Company. Fox, Jonathan, and Libby Haight (eds.). 2010. Subsidizing Inequality: Mexican Corn Policy Since NAFTA. Washington DC: Woodrow Wilson International Center for Scholars. Garc´ıa Antonio, Epifanio. 1999. Im´agenes de mi pueblo, San Juan Guelav´ıa. San Juan Guelav´ıa, Tlac., Oaxaca. Gordillo de Anda, Jerm´an, Alain De Janvry, and Elisabeth Sadoulet. 1999. La segunda reforma agraria de M´exico: Respuestas de familias y comu- nidades, 1990–1994. M´exico: Colegio de M´exico: Fideicomiso Historia de las Am´ericas: Fondo de Cultura Econ´omica. Greenberg, James B. 1989. Blood Ties: Life and Violence in Rural Mexico. Tucson: University of Arizona Press. Guerrero, Jaime. 2009. ‘‘Entra AGP a competencia del mezcal; producir´a 15 mil litros diarios.’’ E-consulta Oaxaca, Noticias. www.e-consulta.com/ oaxaca (accessed February 25, 2010). Hall, Gill, and Christopher Humphrey. 2003. ‘‘Synthesis Report.’’ In Gill Hall and Christopher Humphrey (eds.), Mexico Southern States Development Strategy, Volume 1. Online Report: The World Bank. Havnevik, Kjell, Deborah Fahy Bryceson, Lars-Erik Birgega˚rd, Prosper Matondi, and Atakilte Beyene. 2007. ‘‘African Agriculture and the World 116 Mexican Studies/Estudios Mexicanos
  • 33. Bank: Development or Impoverishment?’’ Nordic African Institute, Policy Dialogue No.1. Report based on the workshop organized by the Nordic Africa Institute, Uppala, March 2007. Stockholm, Sweden: Nordiska Afrikainstitutet (The Nordic Africa Institute). Hern´andez, Pedro. 1984. Anecdotas narradas por el Sen˜or Pedro Hern´andez en Zapoteco de San Juan Guelav´ıa y en Espan˜ol. M´exico: Instituto Lingu¨istico de Verano. INEGI (Instituto Nacional de Estad´ıstica Geograf´ıa e Informaci´on). 1997. El ma´ız en el estado de Oaxaca. Aguascalientes, M´exico: Instituto Nacional de Estad´ıstica Geograf´ıa e Informaci´on (INEGI). ———. 2000. XII Censo general de poblaci´on y vivienda 2000: principales resultos por localidad, Oaxaca. M´exico: Instituto Nacional de Estad´ıstica Geograf´ıa e Informaci´on (INEGI). www.inegi.gob.mx. ———. 2007. Programa de Certificaci´on de Derechos Ejidales y Titulaci´on de Solares, PROCEDE. Oaxaca: abril 1992 – diciembre 2007. Oaxaca, M´exico: Instituto Nacional de Estad´ıstica Geograf´ıa e Informaci´on (INEGI). Kearney, Michael. 1972. The Winds of Ixtepeji: World View and Society in a Zapotec Town. New York: Holt, Rinehart and Winston, Inc. ———. 1996. Reconceptualizing the Peasantry: Anthropology in Global Perspective. Boulder, Co.: Westview Press. Magan˜a, V´ıctor O., Jorge L. V´azquez, Jos´e L. P´erez, and Joel B. P´erez. 2003. ‘‘Impact of El Nin˜o on precipitation in Mexico.’’ Geof´ısica Internacional 42: 313–330. Mendieta y N´un˜ez, Lucio. 1960. Efectos sociales de la reforma agraria en tres comunidades ejidales de la Republica Mexicana. M´exico: Universidad Nacional Aut´onoma de M´exico. Myhre, David. 1996. ‘‘Appropriate Agricultural Credit: A Missing Piece of Agrarian Reform in Mexico.’’ In Laura Randall (ed.), Reforming Mexico’s Agrarian Reform, 117–138. Armonk, NY: M.E. Sharpe. ———. 1998. ‘‘The Achilles’ Heel of the Reforms: The Rural Finance System.’’ In Wayne A. Cornelius and David Myhre (eds.), The Transformation of Rural Mexico: Reforming the Ejido Sector, 39–65. La Jolla: Center for U.S.-Mexican Studies, University of California, San Diego. Nadal, Alejandro. 1999. ‘‘Maize in Mexico. Some Environmental Implications for the North American Free Trade Agreement (NAFTA).’’ In Environment and Trade Series, No. 6 — Issue Study 1: Assessing Environmental Effects of the North American Free Trade Agreement (NAFTA). Montreal, Canada: Commission for Environmental Cooperation. ———. 2000. The Environment and Social Impacts of Economic Liberalization on Corn Production in Mexico. A Study Commissioned by Oxfam GB and WWF International. Geneva: Oxfam and WWF International. ———. 2002. Corn in NAFTA: Eight Years After. www.cec.org/files/PDF/ ECONOMY/Corn-NAFTA_en.pdf (accessed February 9, 2008). Browning, Mexican Agricultural Restructuring after NAFTA 117
  • 34. Nader, Laura. 1964. Talea and Juquila: A Comparison of Zapotec Social Organization. Berkeley and New York: University of California Press, Kraus Reprint (University of California Publications in American Archaeology and Ethnology, v. 48, no. 3). Nash, June. 1967. ‘‘Death as a Way of Life: The Increasing Resort to Homicide in a Mexican Indian Town.’’ American Anthropologist 69: 455–470. ———. 2004. ‘‘Beyond Resistance and Protest: The Maya Quest for Autonomy.’’ In John M. Watanabe and Edward F. Fischer (eds.), Pluralizing Ethnography: Comparison and Representation in Maya Cultures, Histories, and Identities, 163–198. Santa Fe: School of American Research Press. Nuijten, Monique. 2004. ‘‘Peasant ‘Participation,’ Rural Property and the State in Western Mexico.’’ Journal of Peasant Studies 31: 181–209. Oaxaca Libre. 2007. Pacta URO con Coca Cola explotaci´on de agua por dinero para campan˜as: APPO. Oaxaca: Oaxaca Libre. www.oaxacalibre.org (accessed June 5, 2008). Otero, Gerardo. 1999. Farewell to the Peasantry? Political Class Formation in Rural Mexico. Boulder, Co.: Westview Press. Palmer-Rubin, Brian. 2010. ‘‘Is Decentralization the Answer? Lessons from Alianza para el Campo.’’ In Jonathan Fox and Libby Haight (eds.), Subsidizing Inequality: Mexican Corn Policy Since NAFTA, 153–161. Washington, D.C.: Woodrow Wilson International Center for Scholars. Puyana, Alicia, and Jos´e Romero. 2004. Evaluaci´on integral de los impactos e instumentaci´on del cap´ıtulo agropecuario del TLCAN. M´exico: FLACSO and El Colegio de M´exico. Robles Berlanga, Faustino. 2010. ‘‘A Long-Term View: Comparing the Results of Mexico’s 1991 and 2007 Agricultural Censuses.’’ In Jonathan Fox and Libby Haight (eds.), Subsidizing Inequality: Mexican Corn Policy Since NAFTA, 173–183. Washington, D.C.: Woodrow Wilson International Center for Scholars. SAGARPA-SIAP. 2009. Database: Secretaria de Agricultura, Ganader´ıa, Desarrollo Rural, Pesca y Alimentaci´on (SAGARPA)—Servicio de Informaci´on Agroalimentaria y Pesquera (SIAP). www.siap.sagarpa. gob.mx (accessed February 16, 2009). Sesia, Paola. 2003. ‘‘Repeasantization and Decommodification of Indigenous Agriculture: Coffee, Corn, and Food Security in Oaxaca.’’ In Casey Walsh, Lila Emma Ferry, Gabriela Sota Laveaga, Paola Sesia, and Sarah Hill (eds.), The Social Relations of Mexican Commodities: Power, Production, and Place. La Jolla, CA: Center for U.S.-Mexican Studies, University of California, San Diego. Stephen, Lynn. 2005a. ‘‘Women’s Weaving Cooperatives in Oaxaca: An Indigenous Response to Neoliberalism.’’ Critique of Anthropology 25: 253–278. ———. 2005b. Zapotec Women: Gender, Class, and Ethnicity in Globalized Oaxaca. Durham: Duke University Press. ———. 2007. Transborder Lives: Indigenous Oaxacans in Mexico, California, and Oregon. Durham and London: Duke University Press. 118 Mexican Studies/Estudios Mexicanos
  • 35. Taylor, William. 1972. Landlord and Peasant in Colonial Oaxaca. Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press. Torres, Mar´ıa Elena Mart´ınez. 2004. ‘‘Survival Strategies in Neoliberal Markets: Peasant Organizations and Organic Coffee in Chiapas.’’ In Gerardo Otero (ed.), Mexico in Transition: Neoliberal Globalism, the State and Civil Society (Globalization and the Semi-periphery: Impacts, Opposition, Alternatives), 169–185. London and New York: Zed Books. USDA ERS. 2009. Foreign Agricultural Trade of the United States (FATUS) Database: USDA, Economic Research Service. www.ers.usda.gov/Data/ fatus/ (accessed February 9, 2009). USDA FAS. 2004. ‘‘GAIN Report: Mexico: Agricultural Situation: Summary of Mexican Government Study on the Effects of NAFTA on Mexican Agriculture.’’ GAIN Report No. MX4070: USDA, Foreign Agricultural Service. www.fas.usda.gov (accessed February 16, 2008). ———. 2008. ‘‘GAIN Report: Mexico: Grain and Feed, Annual Grain and Feed Report, 2008.’’ GAIN Report No. MX8017: USDA, Foreign Agricultural Service. www.fas.usda.gov (accessed February 16, 2009). ———. 2009. ‘‘Grain: World Markets and Trade.’’ USDA, Foreign Agricultural Service. www.fas.usda.gov/grain/circular/2009/01-09/grainfull01-09.pdf (accessed February 12, 2009). Wise, Timothy A. 2010a. ‘‘The Costs to Mexican Producers of U.S. Agricultural Policies.’’ In Mexican Rural Development Research Report, No. 7. Washington D. C.: Woodrow Wilson International Center for Scholars. www.wilsoncenter.org/DesarrolloRuralMexicano (accessed June 10, 2012). ———. 2010b. ‘‘The Impacts of U.S. Agricultural Policies on Mexican Producers.’’ In Jonathan Fox and Libby Haight (eds.), Subsidizing Inequality: Mexican Corn Policy Since NAFTA: Washington, D.C.: Woodrow Wilson International Center for Scholars. Wolf, Eric. 1957. ‘‘Closed Corporate Peasant Communities in Mesoamerica and Central Java.’’ Southwestern Journal of Anthropology 13: 1–18. Y´unez-Naude, Antonio. 2002. Lessons from NAFTA: The Case of NAFTA’s Agricultural Sector. Washington, D.C.: Office of the Chief Economist for Latin America and the Caribbean, The World Bank. Y´unez-Naude, Antonio, and Fernando Barceinas Paredes. 2004. The Agriculture of Mexico After Ten Years of NAFTA Implementation. Agustinas, Chile: Central Bank of Chile. www.bcentral.cl/eng/stdpub/ studies/workingpaper (accessed March 14, 2008). Zahniser, Steven. 2007. NAFTA at 13: Implementation Nears Completion. Document No. WRS-07-01: Economic Research Service, USDA. www.ers.usda.gov (accessed February 12, 2008). Zahniser, Steven, and William Coyle. 2004. U.S. - Mexico Corn Trade During the NAFTA Era: New Twists to an Old Story. Document No. FDS-04D-01: Economic Research Service, USDA. www.ers.usda.gov (accessed February 12, 2008). Browning, Mexican Agricultural Restructuring after NAFTA 119