SlideShare a Scribd company logo
1 of 42
Download to read offline
Effects of an Energy Policy in the Industrial Sector
The Australian Market Case
Selma Dogic, Meihua Huang, Mianfeng Liu, Syed N. Miah, Qinpeng Wang,
Michael S. Williams, and Yang Yang
Department of Economics, Georgia Institute of Technology
December 02, 2014
Abstract
This paper aims to depict the market for electricity in the industrial sector of Australia	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
and to show the impacts that a government intervention would have. Specifically, this	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
paper investigates the effectiveness of the Australia Clean Energy Act of 2011 by	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
examining the industry response in regard to the demand of electricity and the output	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
of	goods.
Keywords: Energy market, energy intensive industries, industrial energy demand
JEL Codes: D00, D4, Q4
1 Introduction
This paper aims to depict the market for energy in the industrial sector of Australia and to	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
show the impact that a government intervention would have. Specifically, this paper	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
investigates the effectiveness of Australia’s Clean Energy Act of 2011 by examining the tax	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
policy, as well as its repeal, and understanding industry’s response in regards to its	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
demand of energy and its output of goods. The results from this research will better inform	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
the role that governments should or should not play in markets and it will give greater	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
insight into the US’s Clean Air Act, a policy similar to the Australian Clean Energy Act. In	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
particular, the Environmental Protection Agency (EPA), following President Obama’s	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
directive, will set flexible carbon pollution standards, regulations or guidelines, as	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
appropriate, for new power plants, modified and reconstructed power plants, and existing	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
power plants under Section 111 of the Clean Air Act (EPA, 2014). This research will cast	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
new light on the costs and benefits of the performance standards and regulations	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
underway	in	the	US.		
1.1 Policy History and Framework	
In 2011 the Australian government proposed a Clean Energy Plan that aimed to reduce	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
carbon emissions, encouraging energy efficiency, and increasing the use of clean energy.	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
The Plan was designed to reduce greenhouse gas emissions by 5% by 2020 (compared to	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
2000 levels) and by 80% by 2050 (Parliament, A., 2011). However, these aggressive targets	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
do not strictly refer to domestic reductions. It is estimated that Australia will have to rely	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
	
	
1
on purchasing permits from other countries to meet this overall target. To be more specific,	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
eventually 55% of Australian tax dollars are paying firms from the rest of the world to	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
reduce their emissions (Robson, 2013). Related legislation in the Clean Energy Act of 2011	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
introduced	a	carbon	pricing	mechanism	in	two	phases.		
	
The first phase implemented permits on emissions with no cap; in essence these permits	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
acted much like a carbon tax that put a price on Australia’s carbon pollution. This was	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
applied to Australia’s largest carbon emitters (also called liable entities). Under the carbon	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
pricing mechanism, an entity was liable if it was responsible for one or more facilities that	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
emitted a covered scope of one emission of 25,000 tons of carbon dioxide equivalent	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
(CO2e) or more in an eligible financial year. For each of these financial years, liable entities	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
had to surrender one eligible emissions unit for every ton of CO2e that they produced.	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
Entities would have the opportunity to acquire eligible emissions units by purchasing	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
carbon units at a fixed price ($23 per unit in 2012-2013, $24.15 in 2013-2014) from the	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
Clean Energy Regulator or through the creation of eligible Australian Carbon Credit Units	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
(ACCUs) through the Carbon Farming Initiative with emission avoidance activities. The	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
emission avoidance activities included storing carbon in living biomass, dead organic	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
matter or soil. As a context of the fixed price mechanism, the EU price as of August 9th,	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
2013	was	€4.48,	or	$6.50,	which	is	roughly	27%	of	the	carbon	tax	in	Australia	in	2013.	
		
	
	
2
Entities could also purchase carbon units and eligible ACCUs in the secondary market from	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
others who held such units (the use of international permits to meet the requirement was	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
not allowed during the fixed price period); or with industry assistance from the Jobs and	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
Competitiveness Program. The Jobs and Competitiveness Program was aimed at providing	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
assistance to entities that were conducting emissions-intensive and trade-exposed	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
activities (EITE) such that they faced high carbon costs but were unable to pass these costs	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
to global markets. The most EITE activities, such as aluminum production, steel	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
manufacturing, pulp and paper manufacturing, glass making, cement production and	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
petroleum refining, would receive assistance to cover 94.5% of industry average carbon	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
costs in the first year of the carbon price, with less EITE activities to receive assistance to	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
cover 66% of industry average carbon costs 	(Clean Energy Regulator, 2013). Eventually, if	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
a liable entity did not surrender any or enough units, it would be liable for a “unit shortfall	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
charge” at 130% of the price for the relevant financial year multiplied by the number of	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
shortfall units. The carbon pricing mechanism covered a range of large businesses and	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
industrial facilities (around 370 businesses) which were responsible for approximately	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
60% of Australia’s carbon emissions. Generally, smaller businesses or households would	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
not	be	affected.		
	
Under the initial policy design, the second phase was to be implemented in 2015 with a	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
flexible price or cap and trade scheme. However, the carbon pricing mechanism had been	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
abolished	in	July	of	2014	with	the	repeal	of	the	Clean	Energy	Act	of	2011.	
	
	
3
1.2 Costs and Benefits of the Policy
Expected	pros	and	cons	of	the	policy	before	implementation	are	summarized	as	follows:	
● The	carbon	tax	will	incentivize	the	industry	to	reduce	emissions.		
It was expected that emissions in the electricity sector would decrease right after	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
the introduction of the carbon tax. According to Australia’s national greenhouse	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
accounts published by the Australian Department of the Environment, emissions	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
from the electricity sector have been falling since 2008/2009, when electricity	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
emissions fell by nearly 12% mainly due to the reduction of demand and rise of	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
retail electricity price. With the introduction of the carbon tax, the price of an	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
electricity input (such as black coal) is expected to rise. From a standard producer	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
theory, in the long run, the electricity producer may switch to alternative inputs	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
with lower emissions such as hydrogen engines or solar power, and the tax will	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
reduce consumer demand as electricity becomes less affordable. However, the effect	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
on overall emissions is not as strong as indicated by Robson (2013). In his paper,	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
Robson wrote that the carbon tax will lead to the reduction of domestic emissions	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
levels below projected “business as usual” cases, but not the absolute level, which is	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
not expected to fall until 2043. The figure below depicts Australia’s energy	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
consumption by fuel type between the years of 2010 and 2013. Between the years of	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
2011/2012 and 2012/2013 Australia’s consumption of renewable energy grew by	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
11.5%	while	its	consumption	of	coal	decreased	by	almost	6%.		
	
	
4
Figure	1.	Australian	Energy	Consumption	by	Fuel	Type	(BREE,	2014) 	
● The	carbon	tax	will	help	raise	revenue	for	the	government.		
The revenue raised could be used to reduce income tax (by increasing the tax-free	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
threshold). It could also increase pensions and welfare payments to cover expected	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
price increases; the new tax revenue could be used to introduce compensation for	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
some	affected	industries	and	repair	the	damage	caused	by	environmental	pollution.	
● The carbon tax will lead to a socially efficient outcome by removing negative	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
externalities.	
Carbon pollution is a negative externality, which imposes a cost for the whole	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
society instead of the consumer alone. It is postulated that the emissions intensive	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
industries will create excessive carbon pollutions as negative externalities.	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
	
	
5
Therefore, the tax is a means to internalize the externality such that those who	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
cause environmental cost are made to pay the full social cost of their actions. With	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
the tax introduced as the external cost, demand will fall and the new equilibrium	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
will	be	socially	efficient.		
● The optimal level of carbon tax cannot be known in advance without several rounds of	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
changes,	making	it	politically	vulnerable.		
Robson (2013) points out that internationally, the cap and trade scheme is more	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
popular. Although the carbon tax policy with perfect information can lead to the	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
same outcome as a cap and trade scheme, in reality, the perfect information	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
assumption is shaky. A carbon tax is preferred in circumstances where the marginal	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
benefit curve is relatively flat and the marginal cost curve is relatively steep, which	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
may	not	be	the	case,	argued	by	Robson	(2013).	 	
● The	carbon	tax	will	have	economic	and	fiscal	effects	on	Australian	economy.		
The carbon tax may have macroeconomic outcomes such as GDP losses and	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
unemployment. A number of researchers are supporting this argument. For	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
instance, McKibbin et al (2010) evaluated the costs of commitments under the	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
Copenhagen for Australia: the GDP loss in 2020 is estimated to be -6.3%. In	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
addition, Siriwardana et al (2011) projects a 0.75% rise in the consumer price index	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
and a -0.68% decrease in GDP as affected by the carbon tax policy. Siriwardana et al	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
(2011) also estimated that the price of electricity will rise by about 26% in the short	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
run and by 43% above business as usual by the Australian government model.	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
	
	
6
Finally, the government expects the relative reduction in real wages compared to	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
baseline to be much steeper than the overall reduction in GDP, which will cause job	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
losses	in	certain	sectors.	 	
● The carbon tax will likely result in the shift of production to nations without the tax or	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
where	the	tax	is	low.		
This	defeats	the	purpose	of	cutting	carbon	emissions	as	a	global	joint	effort.		
	 	
1.3 Impact
The true economic consequences of the legislation can be examined by observing its impact	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
on specific segments of the economy. Initial projections suggested that the legislation	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
would have a modest overall effect on most aggregate economic variables. However,	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
belying the negligible projected impacts on real GDP and inflation were significant actual or	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
realized effects that were detrimental to specific industries and groups within the economy.	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
The majority of the 75,000 businesses liable to pay the tax did not meet the requirements	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
of the Jobs and Competitiveness Program. That is, they were not EITE entities and,	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
therefore, did not receive assistance to help absorb the higher carbon costs. Among such	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
firms, industry surveys that included the service, manufacturing and construction	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
industries suggest that firms in less competitive markets had a greater tendency to pass on	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
higher energy input costs to consumers (smaller businesses and households). In contrast,	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
firms in more competitive markets were more likely to incur the higher costs and accept	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
lower profits. In some cases - particularly in industries reliant on energy such as food	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
	
	
7
processing, plastics and chemicals, metal manufacturing and oil refining - there has been a	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
marked reduction in planned investment and even some relocation of production facilities	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
offshore. While higher energy bills (namely electricity and gas) were the chief cost-related	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
difficulties faced by firms, the tax also added to rising packaging, transport and other	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
expenses that involve the use of non-renewable energy. This coincided with the largest	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
price	increase	for	electricity	and	gas	in	Australia	since	the	early	1980s	(Ai	Group,	2013).
	
The Clean Energy Act was designed to raise producers' costs, leading to higher output	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
prices faced by businesses and consumers who would then be compensated by the	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
government. Half of all businesses surveyed six months after the implementation of the tax	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
reported higher input costs (to which electricity costs were a major contributor). From the	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
policymakers’ perspective, the problem was that in many sectors the anticipated increase	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
in output prices did not occur broadly. As mentioned above, there has been a clear	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
relationship between competition and price changes in response to the policy: the more	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
elastic the demand for output in a given market (with respect to output price), the less	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
likely firms in that market were to pass on higher input costs to the consumer. For	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
example, while the overwhelming majority of firms in the highly competitive food	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
manufacturing industry reported input price increases, only a tenth of those firms raised	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
their prices. Meanwhile firms enjoying low demand elasticities such as producers of	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
pharmaceutical products and transport equipment were able to raise prices proportionally.	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
Trade-exposed industries, which by definition face regional and global competition, were	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
	
	
8
also found to have difficulties in passing through higher input costs. Service firms, which	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
make up the largest component of Australia's GDP composition and are less trade-exposed,	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
appear	to	have	had	greater	price	pass-through	ability,	accordingly.		
What emerges from considering the micro-level effects of the tax is that there were groups	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
that benefited from the policy and those that were adversely affected. Firms with pricing	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
power or full compensation for the cost of the permits had a means of capturing additional	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
profits. Similarly, businesses that had low carbon output relative to competitors had a way	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
to undercut competitors' prices. Corporate services firms such as accounting and	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
consulting businesses also received some demand-side assistance from the tax because of	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
businesses seeking advice on absorbing high energy costs. In contrast, power sector firms	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
(excluding renewable energy producers) were directly harmed by the tax. Liable entities	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
that did not receive full compensation - especially those in more competitive markets -	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
faced higher carbon costs as well. Finally, consumers also bore some of the cost burden,	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
mostly	in	the	form	of	higher	electricity	prices.	
	
	
9
Figure	2.	Electricity	spot	prices:	weekly	volume	weighted	average	spot	prices	(AER,	2014)	
	
While the sector-specific effects are somewhat clear, the broader level trends in the	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
economy have yielded less information about the policy's impacts. The policy's	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
implementation has coincided with unfavorable movements in key economic variables. For	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
example, unemployment began to steadily increase after the July 2012 implementation of	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
the tax despite falling for 11 of the 12 previous quarters. Total job losses also began a	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
steady rise. In the year following the tax's introduction, GDP growth declined from 3.6% to	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
	
	
10
2.4% (OECD, 2014). But a precise relationship between macroeconomic variable	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
movements and the policy cannot be established yet. The aforementioned events do not	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
necessarily imply a causal relationship with the tax. In fact, the only events that can be	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
directly traced to the policy are increased electricity prices and a mild contribution to	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
inflation.	
	
Even employment movements that were sharper than the average across all industries	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
such as the 29% decline in mining employment from August 2013 to one year onward are	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
better explained by other factors such as falling commodity prices (Bruce Einhom, 2014).	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
This could be interpreted as meaning that the policy did not harm the economy. But as	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
evidenced by its impact on competitive firm profits and consumer welfare, there were clear	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
detrimental effects on certain actors within the economy. Moreover, this can alternatively	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
be interpreted as evidence that the policy may not have adequately disincentivized carbon	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
emission: If the effect of the carbon tax were strong enough to induce firms to change their	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
production processes, then rises in the unemployment rate would be better explained by	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
the increase in energy costs (assuming that firms would reduce employment in the	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
short-run to respond to rising energy costs before implementing other cost-reduction	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
measures such as switching to alternative energy sources). It is also of interest to consider	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
that the electricity price increases that firms faced after July 2012 were driven by	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
additional	factors	as	well	such	as	rising	network	costs.	
	
	
	
11
As initially expected, producers of alternative energies were among the beneficiaries of the	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
policy. But a rapid shift in the sector’s outlook between enforcement and abandonment of	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
the policy illustrate an important point. Total investment in the nation's renewable energy	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
sector doubled in the first full year of the carbon tax (Giles Parkinson, 2014). Post-repeal,	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
there was a steep drop off in such financing. Australia is now on track to record its lowest	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
level of asset financing for large-scale renewables since 2002 in the current year. Each of	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
the three largest firms investing in Australia's renewable energy sector have cited	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
uncertainty about the current government's RET as the primary reason for the decline in	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
investment. This highlights an important point to be observed: regardless of the pros and	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
cons of environmental regulation, policy consistency is needed to fully determine whether	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
it	can	be	successful	or	not.	
		
The prospect and realization of higher energy prices, reduced investment and international	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
competitiveness as well as spillover price increases in other energy-reliant markets	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
produced a strong political opposition to the carbon tax. The legislation was also construed	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
as favorable to firms with monopoly power. As a result, it was anticompetitive, according to	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
this view. In addition, there was a perceived lack of balance with respect to responsibility	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
and liability. While ten percent of the economy accounts for ninety percent of carbon	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
pollution, the resulting higher energy prices and cost pressures affected a much larger	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
proportion of the economy than the offending ten percent. Such a view does not, however,	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
give consideration to the benefits gained from the carbon tax; for example, increased future	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
	
	
12
living standards. These factors all contributed to the political developments that lead to	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
repeal.	
	
1.4 State of the Australian Economy		
If the Australian experience with environmentally-focused government intervention is seen	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
as an experiment upon which other industrialized countries can base their policies, then	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
the unique characteristics of the Australian economy should be accounted for before any	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
generalizations can be made about the impact of such legislation. Since 1983, Australia has	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
seen the floating of its currency to make exchange rates more flexible, transformation of	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
the financial system through deregulation and substantial reduction of trade barriers such	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
as import quotas and tariffs, among many other economically liberal changes to its	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
economy. These reforms have made Australia the third freest economy in the world (The	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
Heritage	Foundation,	2014).	 	
		
Australia is one of the few industrialized countries that weathered the recent global	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
recession without any significant slump in its economic performance. GDP growth rates	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
progressively increased from 1.7% at the height of the global recession in mid-2009 to	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
3.7% in 2012 (The World Bank, n.d.). One of the key drivers of economic growth has been	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
strong investment in the resource sector in response to what has been called "a mining	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
boom". Over the last decade, investment in this segment of the economy has quadrupled	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
while the capital stock has grown by 300% (The Commonwealth of Australia, 2013). This	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
	
	
13
pouring of resources into resources has largely been the result of China's unprecedented	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
growth over the same time period. In particular, there has been great demand for iron ore	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
and coal, which are Australia's top export products. Iron ore is a key input in making the	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
steel used for public infrastructure and housing projects while coal supplies the majority of	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
China's energy consumption. With the country becoming Australia's biggest trade partner,	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
investment in mining drove about half of GDP growth in 2011 (The Economist, 2012). In	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
short,	China's	development	has	helped	propel	Australia's	recent	prosperity.	
	
In part for the same reason, the most recent growth projections for Australia have been	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
dimmer than usual. China's growth rate is at the slowest pace since the global recession	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
five years ago (The World Bank, n.d). The uncertainty surrounding China's economy, falling	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
commodity prices and the increasing cost of doing business - partly because of regulatory	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
burden (Productivity Commission, 2014) - has led to a decline in investment in the	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
Australian resource sector. With mining and related sectors accounting for 19% of Gross	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
Domestic Product (Tim Colebatch, 2012), investment in these sectors is an important part	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
of the growth picture. Therefore, the reduced investment is expected to dampen economic	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
growth in coming years and, indeed, there has already been a noticeable slow down (The	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
Commonwealth	of	Australia,	2013;	Hannam,	2014).		
	
	
	
	
	
14
Figure	3.	Australian	GDP	growth	(Reserve	bank	of	Australia,	2014)	
	
At the same time, new drivers of growth are needed to strengthen growth prospects	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
moving forward and lower the risk of eventually falling into a recession. The Government	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
of Australia now expects the economy to transition from having its growth be based on	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
resource sectors to growth based on non-resource sector output (The Commonwealth of	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
Australia, 2013). However, this transition will be slow as non-resource based growth has	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
	
	
15
been subdued. Even with resource sectors moving from the investment phase to the	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
production phase and the exports coming out of those sectors expected to make a larger	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
contribution to growth, production outside of resource sectors will need to expand to fill	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
the void created by falling investment. Exports may also be constrained by a strong	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
currency.	
	
While Australia's national debt is among the lowest in the developed world, its year-to-year	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
budget position has diminished in recent years, with deficits expected every year up to	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
2024 without a policy change (The Commonwealth of Australia, 2013). Part of this	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
deterioration is due to a weaker economic outlook and the resulting reduced public	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
revenue. Future growth is expected to be led by growth outside of the mining and natural	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
resource sectors and such growth has appeared to be sluggish. As a result, real GDP is	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
forecast to grow at 2.5 % in 2014-15, compared to the 3 % estimate for 2013. According to	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
the ruling Liberal government's estimates, the other reason for the weakening of the	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
budget position is that expenditures are needed to address unresolved fiscal matters from	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
the outgoing Labor party's administration of government. These include a grant to the	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
Reserve Bank of Australia to help withstand shocks ($8.8 Billion) , providing additional	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
funding for a policy relating to offshore processing of illegal maritime arrivals ($1.2 billion),	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
restoring outlays for a fair funding agreement for Australian schools ($1.2 Billion) and	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
following up on a backlog of announced but unlegislated tax and pension measures ($2.9	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
billion)	(The	Commonwealth	of	Australia,	2013).	
	
	
16
The factors mentioned up to this point provide some context for evaluating the impact of	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
the carbon tax on the Australian economy. But the effect of the tax on macroeconomic	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
variables should be considered alongside more sector-specific information to properly	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
gauge what the true consequences of the policy are. A microeconomic accounting for the	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
policy's impact revealed significant factors that were detrimental to specific industries and	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
groups within the economy. Thus the Australian carbon tax should be viewed through the	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
prism of an economy with a resource sector that is expected to slow down and is in need of	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
non-resource drivers of growth, which signifies that the effect of the policy on individual	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
groups	and	actors	in	the	economy	are	of	paramount	importance.	
		
The weaker economic outlook given by government projections underscores the need to	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
emphasize policies that improve productivity, allow firms to be more efficient and reduce	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
the regulatory burden on businesses and individuals. Ending the carbon tax was expected	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
to reduce cost pressures on households and businesses and is consistent with meeting	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
these needs. Predictably, the Australian senate vote repealing the tax coincided with a	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
surge in business confidence (National Australia Bank, 2014). The repeal has also been	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
linked to above-average consumer optimism as reduced energy costs offset some of the	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
concerns over stagnant wages, rising unemployment and high housing prices (National	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
Australia Bank, 2014). Annual household savings produced by the repeal may vary	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
between $250 and $550 per household. Much of these savings are on electricity costs. In	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
addition, some firms that received full compensation from the government (essentially	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
	
	
17
getting free pollution permits) were known to pass higher costs on to consumers	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
regardless,	keeping	the	difference	as	profit.	The	repeal	has	ended	this	practice.	
		
It seems clear that the carbon tax in Australia reshuffled economic welfare from certain	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
groups to others. It likely affected business and consumer sentiment, which are important	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
for the country's economic performance. But broad economy-wide impacts have not been	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
attributed to the policy. Since the United States and Australian economies are structurally	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
similar, this might have implications for what the consequences of environmental	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
regulation could be in the United States. Australia serves as a reasonable test tube as long	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
as some of the factors mentioned above are accounted for (e.g. the mining boom, growth	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
spurred by China's development and the transition to non-resource drivers of growth).	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
Assuming an identical policy in the US, analyzing its merits might be a matter of	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
determining whether a rise in electricity costs for consumers and businesses is an	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
acceptable	price	for	achieving	environmental	objectives.
2 Models
In order to investigate the Australian policy and its effect on industry, it is imperative to	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
understand what role energy plays in the industrial sector. Energy is an important input to	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
the production process; it plays a similar role to labor and capital. The industrial	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
consumption of energy can be altered by either using an alternative energy source, using a	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
more energy efficient model, or by changing the utilization of capital stock. Only the last	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
	
	
18
option can be implemented in the short run, implying that in the short run in order for a	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
firm to decrease its energy consumption it must decrease its production. Industrial demand	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
for energy follows the fundamental relationship between price and quantity, as price of	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
energy increases the demand for energy decreases (all else equal). Hill and Cao (2012)	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
showed in their paper that the short run price elasticity for electricity is .24, showing that a	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
1% increase in the price of electricity leads to a .24% decrease in the demand for electricity	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
(all else equal). The authors also showed that there is a positive relationship between gross	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
value added (GVA) and the demand for electricity, which is a logical deduction because as	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
firms	produce	more	their	demand	for	electricity	rises.	
		
The associated effects of a change in electricity price give a clear indication of what the	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
expected effects of the regulation of energy are. Supply and demand forces, including	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
regulations, can be measured using price. Usually new regulations of any market will make	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
prices rise and deregulation will make prices fall. An abrupt long-term change in the price	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
trendline is a good indication that a change in regulation has been implemented. Wholesale	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
market prices are the first-line indication of the effects of supply and demand forces, and	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
the prices of the wholesale electricity markets of Australia are the prices of which this	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
research	will	focus	to	examine	the	effects	of	regulation.	
	
	
	
	
	
19
2.1 Data Collection
The following empirical model will utilize Australian government published data. Energy	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
consumption data were collected from the Bureau of Resources and Energy Economics	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
Australian Energy Statistics publication. Electricity prices are sourced from the Australian	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
Bureau of Statistics Producer Index Series. Output data was obtained from the Australian	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
Bureau of Statistics National Accounts Branch publications. The research also defines	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
energy intensive industries based on energy consumption data published by the Bureau of	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
Resources and Energy Economics. This allows for further understanding of the impact on	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
energy	intensive	sectors	and	the	effectiveness	of	the	Jobs	and	Competitiveness	Program.	
		
2.2 Empirical Models
This paper uses three different models to measure the effectiveness of the Australian policy	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
: time-series, simultaneous equations, and ANOVA. The ANOVA and time-series models	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
were used to analyze the relationship between average electricity price and the carbon tax	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
policy. The simultaneous models built the aggregate demand and supply and were utilized	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
to	demonstrate	how	the	policy	affect	the	manufacture	industry	market.	
2.2.1 Time-series Model
2.2.1.1 Theortical Model
This model utilizes a combined regression-time series model to investigate the relationship	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
between	electricity	price	and	the	carbon	tax	policy.	The	form	of	the	model	is	
	
	
20
pricet = c + dummy +	 	 	 	 	 	
vt	vt	~	AMAR(p;	q)	
	 	
2.2.1.2 Estimated Model and Results	
In this model, price is the average electricity price from July 2011 to June 2013. As the	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
carbon tax policy of Australia began July 1st, 2012 , the dummy was set to 1 after July 2012.	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
The dummy was used as the only explanatory variable to determine whether it caused a	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
change	to	the	mean	of	the	price.		
		
The	result	is	as	below:		
	
	
	
	
	
	
	
	
	
	
	
	
21
From	the	form,	the	final	regression	function	is	
	
	
	
2.2.1.3 Hypothesis Testing
After doing several tests, it is clear that the regression model satisfied assumptions both in	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
the linear regression part and the MA part. In the regression result, the p-value for the	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
Dummy variable is 0.0001, showing that the carbon tax had a very significant effect to the	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
electricity price. As t=4.94 and p¡=0.05 for the dummy variable, it is possible to conclude	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
that the carbon tax policy made a significant effect to the electricity price. After the policy	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
began, the average electricity price raised about $17.9 per megawatt hour. However, the	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
success of the policy is ambiguous. If the demand elasticity of electricity is big enough, it	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
will have a large positive effect to reduce the energy cost; but if the elasticity is	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
considerably small, it will only cause consumers to pay more (subsequently reducing	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
consumer surplus). In order to calculate elasticity, the demand function of electricity must	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
be	determined.	
	
	
	
	
	
	
	
22
Tests	for	the	assumptions:	
1.	Heteroskedasticity	Test:	Breusch-Pagan-Godfrey:	
	
	
	
	
	
	
	
	
	
2.	Unit	Root	test	for	ut	:	
	
	
23
3.	Q-statistics	for	vt:	
	
	
2.2.2 Simultaneous Equations Model
2.2.2.1 Theoretical Models
Simultaneous equations were used to build up a model regarding the aggregate demand	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
and supply in order to estimate whether the policy’s effectiveness. To set up the model, the	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
structural equations must first be designed. Secondly, the equation’s completeness must be	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
ensured (the number of equations is equal to number of endogenous variables). Lastly, the	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
structural equation parameters (depending on characteristics of the model) need to be	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
estimated.	These	steps	produce	the	aggregate	demand	and	supply	equations	as	below:		
qd	=	a0	+	a1	pd	+	a2x1	+	e1
qs	=	b0	+	b1	ps	+	b2y1	+	e2	
where	qd	=	qs	is	the	equilibrium	condition	
	
	
24
Here variable x1 is something that shifts the demand equation but does not shift the supply	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
equation	and	variable	y1	is	something	that	shifts	the	supply	holding	demand	constant.		
2.2.2.2 Estimated Models 	
In this section, manufacturing output (market supply) was used to estimate market	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
demand and producer price index as price sold or purchased. Moreover, variable lelep is	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
the variable that will shift the supply holding demand constant and variable lgdp is the	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
variable that will shift the demand without shifting supply curve. Clearly, the endogenous	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
variables are quantity and ppi, where variable quantity is on the left hand side of the	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
equations and variable ppi is on the right hand side of the equations. The remainder of the	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
variables	are	the	exogenous	ones.	The	simultaneous	equations	models	are	as	below:	
	Demand	:	quantityd	=	a0	+	a1	ppi	+	a2	lgdp	+	a3	quantity2	+	e1	
Supply	:	quantitys	=	b0	+	b1	ppi	+	b2	lelep	+	e2	
where	
variable	quantitys(quantityd	)	=	Manufacture	Sector	Supply(Demand)	variable	
quantity2	=	Manufacture	Sector	Input	
																																				variable	ppi	=	Producer	Price	Index	
													variable	lelep	=	log	of	Average	Electricity	Price		
																																		variable	lgdp	=	log	of	GDP	
		
	
	
	
25
2.2.2.3 Estimated Results		
Normally, OLS provides best linear unbiased estimators, but under the simultaneous	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
equations model OLS is biased. Thus, the estimates from reg3 OLS option might be not	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
good. One could use reg3 in Stata by using 2SLS, yielding consistent estimates for each	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
just-identified or over-identified structural equation in a system. When using 2SLS,	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
however, the structural parameters of each equation are estimated separately. Although	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
the 2SLS estimator for each equation makes use of the information on all of the exogenous	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
and pre-determined variables for the whole system, it ignores the information contained in	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
the excluded endogenous variables in that equation and information contained in the error	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
covariances.	Therefore,	2SLS	is	not	efficient,	and	thus	3SLS	was	used	instead.	
		
Since the three stage least squares model is created by combining the 2SLS notion with SUR	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
Model, iteration over the estimated disturbance covariance matrix and parameter	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
estimates until the parameter estimates converge is preferred by most statisticians. Hence,	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
the best results are expected to be generated by iterated 3SLS. After running the three	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
stage least square regressions with different options (naive OLS, 2SLS, default 3SLS and	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
iterated 3SLS) in Stata, a table with the comparison of the four different models is	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
presented.	Below	are	the	best	(iterated	3SLS)	estimated	demand	and	supply	equations:	
	
Demand	:	quantityd	=	172.20	-	0.03	ppi	+	8.18	lgdp	+	0.37	quantity2	+	e1	
	Supply	:	quantitys	=	62.30	+	0.04	ppi	+	8.71	lelep	+	e2		
	
	
26
From the Stata output, the p-value for the equations are less than 0.0015. Additionally, the	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
model offers other strong evidence: in the iterated 3SLS model, most of the coefficients are	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
statistically significant at the 1% level and only the coefficient on ppi in the supply equation	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
is slightly statistically significant, at the 10% level, and its p-value is approximately 0.086.	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
Therefore, the results are very convincing that the carbon tax policy forced the whole	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
manufacturing	sector	to	produce	less.		
	
After replacing the mean value for variable lgdp, lelep and quantity2, Stata generated the	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
demand and supply curves. It is obvious to see that the manufacturing sector produced less	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
after the government regulation was imposed, indicating that energy intensive industries	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
consume	a	large	proportion	of	energy	for	production.
	
	
27
2.2.2.4 Hypothesis Testing
The basic assumptions such as nonsingularity , uncorrelated with the error term, the rank	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
of the exdogenous variables and asymptotically convergent will hold if the stata doesn’t	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
give us an error or warning. Since Stata generate the output for us, we assume these basic	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
assumptions are satisfied. Another two important specification tests for simultaneous	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
equations regression models are testing of exogeneity and testing of overidentifying	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
restrictions. To test the the endogenity and whether the equations overidentify, Sargan’s	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
(1958)	statistic	or	Basmann’s	(1960)	statistic	were	used.	Results	are	as	below:	
		
By assuming ppi is also an endogenous variable, two unknowns exist in these equations,	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
which are quantity and ppi. On the other hand, the test gives us Hansen-Sargan	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
overidentification statistic, which rejects the null hypothesis that the model is	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
overidentified.		Therefore,	the	model	meets	expectations.	
	
	
	
	
28
2.2.2.5 Interpretation and Intuition
Is the carbon tax policy on manufacture sector really effective? Because variable quantity	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
and ppi are measured by index numbers, it is known that the demand equation represents	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
the demand elasticity of manufactured products. However, −0.03 is inelastic for the	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
quantity demanded, signifying that however the price changes the demand for	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
manufactured products, the effect is not large. And the quantity produced predicted by the	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
models only decreases about 3%. Indeed, the model has room to improve due to the	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
insufficient information. However, the conclusion is logical, because society is heavily	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
reliant on these products (such as food and petroleum products). Clearly, further research	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
needs to be conducted in order to explore the efficiency of the policy and its ability to	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
reduce	energy	consumption	without	sacrificing	social	welfare.		
	
	
29
2.2.3 Analysis of Variance Model
This section investigates how government intervention through the implementation of a	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
carbon tax impacts industrial output with seasonally adjusted GVA (gross value added) as	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
an indicator. Quarterly GVA data from March 2010 to June 2014 were collected from the	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
Australian Bureau of Statistics National Accounts Branch publications. Since it was	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
	
	
30
postulated that the carbon tax policy directly impacts the electricity price while indirectly	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
impacting the industrial output, average quarterly wholesale electricity prices were	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
collected	and	studied	jointly	with	the	GVA	data,	which	are	shown	below.	
	
	
	
	
	
	
	
	
	
	
A preliminary correlation analysis indicates a strong negative correlation (correlation	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
coefficient -0.793) between the electricity price and manufacturing industry output, these	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
results are expected. Figure 3 below depicts the electricity price against manufacturing	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
industry output. A visual inspection reveals that the before and after electricity price and	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
GVA seem to be clustered around different means, suggesting a drastic change incurred by	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
implementing the carbon tax policy. Such a hypothesis leads to a k-means clustering	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
analysis testing whether n observations could be partitioned into k clusters in which each	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
observation belongs to the cluster with the nearest mean, serving as a prototype of the	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
	
	
31
cluster. In this case, only two categories exist: pre- and post- intervention, making k equal	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
to	2.	
	
	
	
	
	
	
	
	
	
	
	
	
	
	
	
	
	
	
The	k-means	clustering	analysis	leads	to	the	following	observations:	
	
	
32
1. Pre- and post- intervention quarterly price and manufacturing GVA are clearly	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
clustered around distinct centroids, indicating the policy intervention incurred a	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
sharp	change	on	electricity	price	and	industry	output.	
2. The centroid GVA of manufacturing of metal products reduced from 4587 to	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
4328 million and the centroid electricity price increased from $30.1 to $55.3 per	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
megawatt	hour	with	the	introduction	of	the	policy.		
	
2.2.3.1 ANOVA Model
A similar approach is the ANOVA (analysis of variance). Considering the introduction of the	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
carbon policy as a treatment, the pre- and post- intervention levels of quarterly	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
manufacturing GVA reveal the effect of the treatment, which justifies the analysis of a	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
one-way	layout	design	of	experiment.	The	model	is	as	follows:	
yi	j	=	hˆ	+	tˆ	+	ri	j	
where	hˆ	is	the	grand	mean,	tˆ	is	the	treatment	effect,	ri	j	is	the	residual.	
	
	
	
	
	
	
	
	
33
The null hypothesis that there is no treatment effect is rejected at the 5x10 -5 level,	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
suggesting that the carbon tax policy has a significant negative impact on the output of the	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
metal	product	manufacturing	industry.	
	
3 Discussion
This research finds that the effects of Australia’s Clean Energy Act of 2011 are clearly	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
measurable and significant. Using several variables, we analyze the time periods directly	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
before and after the bill went into effect. By doing this, the immediate costs and benefits of	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
the	bill	become	obvious,	and	we	find	why	the	bill	was	shortly	repealed.	
	
To the average consumer there was no benefit and only a cost. The only difference the	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
average consumer could measure is an increase in the price of energy. The benefits, a	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
healthier environment and sustained resources, would only be noticeable in the long run,	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
and	would	be	more	difficult	to	quantify.	
	
The policy was implemented in order to reduce CO2e emissions and to encourage the use of	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
alternative energy sources, a seemingly sound policy considering that Australia is the	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
among the heaviest polluting nations in the world. In fact, according to the US Energy	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
Information Administration, in 2011 Australia was the second largest per capita carbon	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
dioxide emitter among the G20 nations. However, it is ambiguous whether or not the policy	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
really targeted the nation’s heaviest polluters. The Jobs and Competitiveness Program	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
	
	
34
offered assistance to entities that were emissions intensive in order to mitigate their higher	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
carbon costs; the program aimed to help soothe the cost disruptions in the market but	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
decreased the impact of the policy as the push to lower emissions and switch to alternative	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
energies	was	weakened.	
	
It is also noteworthy that in 2013, coal was Australia’s second greatest export. Additionally,	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
Australia’s other major exports were emissions intensive, signifying that the country had a	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
comparative advantage in the production of emissions intensive goods and a relatively high	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
opportunity cost of producing goods with low emissions. These factors caused the	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
cost-burden of the tax to be relatively high to consumers. Although the industrial sector	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
noticed an increase in the price of energy as well as a reduction in potential output, many	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
firms were unable to pass along the costs. This was likely the cause of a competitive global	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
market, which means that rather than a tax that led to a reduction of global emissions, the	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
tax led to carbon leakage, thus defeating the purpose of the policy on a macro scale	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
(Australian	Government	Department	of	Foreign	Affairs	and	Trade;	Robson,	A.	2013).		
	
It is arguable that the timing of the bill could have been one of the causes of contention.	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
Shortly after the worst recession since the Great Depression, the passage of a bill that raises	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
energy prices at a rate more than three times that of the already-established EU rate is hard	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
to economically justify, and part of the reason the act was abolished. Job loss increased and	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
	
	
35
GDP growth declined during the 8 quarters that the carbon tax was in effect, something not	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
yet	precisely	attributable	to	the	carbon	tax,	but	certainly	politically	so.	
	
4 Conclusion
The models used in this paper show that the policy had significant impacts in the industrial	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
sector. Tests yield that the tax policy significantly impacted electricity prices. Yet, the	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
effects of the rise in prices could have been offset by the demand elasticity for electricity.	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
The policy caused a sharp reduction in the output of metal products as the policy caused	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
electricity prices to rise. There is convincing evidence that the carbon tax caused the	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
manufacturing industry to produce less. However, due to the nature of inelasticity, the	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
effect of price on demand for manufactured goods is relatively small. In all, the ANOVA test	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
was able to suggest that the policy had a significant effect to reduce metal product	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
manufacturing	output.		
	
It is also noteworthy that the policy faced harsh political opposition. Though a tax seems to	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
be the most efficient form of an environmental regulation, and poses as a revenue to the	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
government, it is impossible to determine the best rate in advance. This causes the tax to	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
fluctuate early in its implementation and, due to its nature, the tax may appear to be	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
unstable	to	the	public	and	unpopular	to	many.		
	
	
	
36
Irrespective of the repeal of the tax in Australia, it serves as a tool for other nations	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
considering similar policies. The greatest lesson to be learned is the impact of the costs to	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
consumers and their perceived benefits. Nations wishing to implement environmental	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
regulations of this kind must seriously consider the political repercussions as well as the	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
economic costs. It has been shown that such a policy not only raises the prices of electricity,	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
but also deeply disrupts the economy without benefiting the environment at a noticeable	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
scale.	
	
Australia’s brief encounter with carbon emissions policy reform did not occur without	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
political repercussions. A bill passed just two years earlier, then repealed due to negative	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
coincidal events rather than amended, brings forth questions of whether the state was	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
effectively governing. With that, some may find it the case that the government would have	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
been more effective by simply lowering the carbon tax to a level more in tune with the	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
proven-effective rates of the European Union. In any case, the Australia Clean Energy Act of	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
2011 was passed, then repealed, and there is much to be learned from the event by	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	 	
countries,	such	as	the	United	States,	that	seek	to	pass	similar	legislation.	
	
	
	
37
References	
AER	(2014).	Industry statistics.	[online:	web]	Viewed:	30
th
	October	2014.		
<http://www.aer.gov.au/Industry-information/industry-statistics>	
Ai	group	(2013).	Ai Group Survey: business pricing responses to Australia’s carbon
tax , the first six months.	[online:	web]	Viewed:	23
nd
	September	2014.		
<http://www.aigroup.com.au/portal/binary/com.epicentric.contentmana	
gement.servlet.ContentDeliveryServlet/LIVE_CONTENT/Publications/Rep
orts/2013/Carbon_price_impacts_Jan_2013_REPORT_FINAL.pdf>		
BREE	(2014).	2014 Australian energy statistics data: Australian total net energy
consumption, by state, by fuel, energy units.	[online:	web]	Viewed:	1st	
December	2014.	
<http://www.bree.gov.au/publications/australian-energy-statistics/	
2014-australian-energy-statistics-data>	
Bruce	Einhom	(2014).	Australian Economy Changes as Exports to China Slow.
[online:web]	Viewed:	25
th
	November	2014.	
<http://www.businessweek.com/articles/2014-09-25/australian-econo
my-chages-as-commodity-exports-to-china-slow>	
Clean	Energy	Regulator	(2013).	Jobs and Competitiveness Program – guidance for
applicants.	V1.2_21/02/13.	Australian	Government.
Giles	Parkinson	(2014). Is this the death of Australia’s renewable energy industry?	
[online:	web]	Viewed:	25
th
	November	2014.
<http://reneweconomy.com.au/2014/is-this-the-death-of-australias-rene
wable-energy-industry-83477>	
McKibbin,	Warwick	J,	Adele	Morris,	and	Peter	J.	Wilcoxen	(2010).	Comparing
Climate Commitments: A Model-Based Analysis of the Copenhagen Accord.		
Discussion	Paper	2010-35,	Cambridge,	Mass.:	Harvard	Project	on	 	
International	Climate	Agreements,	June	2010.	
National	Australia	Bank	(2014).	Monthly business survey.	[online:	web]	Viewed:	
10
th
	November	2014.
<http://business.nab.com.au/wp-content/uploads/2014/08/monthly-bus
iness-survey-july-2014.pdf>	
OECD	(2014).	Economics: Key Tables from OECD.		[online:	web]	Viewed:	10
th
	
November	2014.
<http://www.oecd-ilibrary.org/economics/real-gross-domestic-product-	
forecasts_gdp-kusd-gr-table-en>	
Peter	Hannam	(2014).	Who wins, who loses when the carbon tax goes?
[online:	web]	Viewed:	10
th	
November,	2014.	
<http://www.smh.com.au/business/carbon-economy/who-wins-who-los
es-when-the-carbon-tax-goes-20140709-zt1mm.html>
Productivity	Commission	(2014).	Relative Costs of Doing Business in Australia:
Retail Trade.	Research	Report,	Canberra.	
Reserve	bank	of	Australia	(2014).	The Australian Economy and Financial
Markets. [online:	web]	Viewed:	10
th
	November,	2014.		
<http://www.rba.gov.au/chart-pack/pdf/chart-pack.pdf>	
Robson.	A.	(2013).	Australia’s carbon tax: an economic evaluation.	Department	of		
Accounting,	Finance	and	Economics,	Griffith	University,	Brisbane,		
Australia.	
Siriwardana,	M.,	Meng,	S.,	&	McNeill,	J.	(2011).	The impact of a carbon tax on the
Australian economy: Results from a CGE model.	Business,	Economics	and		
Public	Policy	Working	Papers,	2.	
The	Commonwealth	of	Australia	(2013).	Mid-year economic and fiscal outlook.
	[online:	web]	Viewed:	10
th
	November,	2014.	
<http://www.budget.gov.au/2013-14/content/myefo/download/2013_1
4_MYEFO.pdf>	
The	Economist	(2012).	Australia’s two-track economy hitched to the China
wagon.	[online:	web]	Viewed:	10
th
	November,	2014.
<http://www.economist.com/node/21560914>	
The	Heritage	Foundation	(2014).	2014 index of Economic Freedom-- Australia.
[online:	web]	Viewed:	10
th
	November,	2014.
<http://www.heritage.org/index/country/australia>	
The	World	Bank	(n.d.).	GDP growth (annual %).	[online:	web]	Viewed:	10
th	
November,	2014.	
<http://data.worldbank.org/indicator/NY.GDP.MKTP.KD.ZG>	
Tim	Colebatch	(2012).	Our economic irrationalism.	[online:	web]	Viewed:	8
th
	
November,	2014.
<http://www.smh.com.au/federal-politics/political-opinion/our-economi
c-irrationalism-20120312-1uwde.html>

More Related Content

What's hot

From Ugly Duckling to Superstar: how energy efficiency (almost) got to the to...
From Ugly Duckling to Superstar: how energy efficiency (almost) got to the to...From Ugly Duckling to Superstar: how energy efficiency (almost) got to the to...
From Ugly Duckling to Superstar: how energy efficiency (almost) got to the to...FTI Consulting FR
 
Day 1 Jordan's Energy Efficiency Policies
Day 1 Jordan's Energy Efficiency PoliciesDay 1 Jordan's Energy Efficiency Policies
Day 1 Jordan's Energy Efficiency PoliciesRCREEE
 
Universityofsussex
UniversityofsussexUniversityofsussex
UniversityofsussexAhmad Eid
 
The Global Survey of the Electrical Energy Distribution System: A Review
The Global Survey of the Electrical Energy Distribution System: A ReviewThe Global Survey of the Electrical Energy Distribution System: A Review
The Global Survey of the Electrical Energy Distribution System: A ReviewIJECEIAES
 
Energy: Current Situation and Trends. From Global to Local
Energy: Current Situation and Trends. From Global to LocalEnergy: Current Situation and Trends. From Global to Local
Energy: Current Situation and Trends. From Global to LocalOrkestra
 
China energy roadmap slides
China energy roadmap slidesChina energy roadmap slides
China energy roadmap slidesRoger Atkins
 
De-risking Renewable Energy Investments
De-risking Renewable Energy InvestmentsDe-risking Renewable Energy Investments
De-risking Renewable Energy InvestmentsLászló Árvai
 
Business guide on carbon emission redution and sustainability
Business guide on carbon emission redution and sustainabilityBusiness guide on carbon emission redution and sustainability
Business guide on carbon emission redution and sustainabilityBarney Loehnis
 
OECD Green Talks LIVE - Taxing Energy Use 2019
OECD Green Talks LIVE - Taxing Energy Use 2019OECD Green Talks LIVE - Taxing Energy Use 2019
OECD Green Talks LIVE - Taxing Energy Use 2019OECD Environment
 
25-in-5 - Unlocking Energy Efficiency
25-in-5 - Unlocking Energy Efficiency25-in-5 - Unlocking Energy Efficiency
25-in-5 - Unlocking Energy EfficiencyAndy Bolitho
 
Synopsis & toc global renewable energy 2009 - 2018
Synopsis & toc global renewable energy 2009 - 2018Synopsis & toc global renewable energy 2009 - 2018
Synopsis & toc global renewable energy 2009 - 2018Gyan Research And Analytics
 
Coalition Climate Policy and the National Climate Interest
Coalition Climate Policy and the National Climate InterestCoalition Climate Policy and the National Climate Interest
Coalition Climate Policy and the National Climate InterestThe Climate Institute
 
Slideshare -energy_prices_explained_what_are_feed-in_tariffs_and_the_renewab...
Slideshare  -energy_prices_explained_what_are_feed-in_tariffs_and_the_renewab...Slideshare  -energy_prices_explained_what_are_feed-in_tariffs_and_the_renewab...
Slideshare -energy_prices_explained_what_are_feed-in_tariffs_and_the_renewab...Deeply Digital
 
Carsten Rolle, Executive Director WEC Germany
Carsten Rolle, Executive Director WEC Germany Carsten Rolle, Executive Director WEC Germany
Carsten Rolle, Executive Director WEC Germany WEC Italia
 

What's hot (20)

Comparison of Iran's laws on Improving Energy Efficiency in the Building Sect...
Comparison of Iran's laws on Improving Energy Efficiency in the Building Sect...Comparison of Iran's laws on Improving Energy Efficiency in the Building Sect...
Comparison of Iran's laws on Improving Energy Efficiency in the Building Sect...
 
Epsu
EpsuEpsu
Epsu
 
From Ugly Duckling to Superstar: how energy efficiency (almost) got to the to...
From Ugly Duckling to Superstar: how energy efficiency (almost) got to the to...From Ugly Duckling to Superstar: how energy efficiency (almost) got to the to...
From Ugly Duckling to Superstar: how energy efficiency (almost) got to the to...
 
Solar PV Road Map
Solar PV Road MapSolar PV Road Map
Solar PV Road Map
 
Day 1 Jordan's Energy Efficiency Policies
Day 1 Jordan's Energy Efficiency PoliciesDay 1 Jordan's Energy Efficiency Policies
Day 1 Jordan's Energy Efficiency Policies
 
Universityofsussex
UniversityofsussexUniversityofsussex
Universityofsussex
 
The Global Survey of the Electrical Energy Distribution System: A Review
The Global Survey of the Electrical Energy Distribution System: A ReviewThe Global Survey of the Electrical Energy Distribution System: A Review
The Global Survey of the Electrical Energy Distribution System: A Review
 
Energy: Current Situation and Trends. From Global to Local
Energy: Current Situation and Trends. From Global to LocalEnergy: Current Situation and Trends. From Global to Local
Energy: Current Situation and Trends. From Global to Local
 
China energy roadmap slides
China energy roadmap slidesChina energy roadmap slides
China energy roadmap slides
 
Duke draft 9 21-10
Duke draft 9 21-10Duke draft 9 21-10
Duke draft 9 21-10
 
De-risking Renewable Energy Investments
De-risking Renewable Energy InvestmentsDe-risking Renewable Energy Investments
De-risking Renewable Energy Investments
 
Business guide on carbon emission redution and sustainability
Business guide on carbon emission redution and sustainabilityBusiness guide on carbon emission redution and sustainability
Business guide on carbon emission redution and sustainability
 
OECD Green Talks LIVE - Taxing Energy Use 2019
OECD Green Talks LIVE - Taxing Energy Use 2019OECD Green Talks LIVE - Taxing Energy Use 2019
OECD Green Talks LIVE - Taxing Energy Use 2019
 
25-in-5 - Unlocking Energy Efficiency
25-in-5 - Unlocking Energy Efficiency25-in-5 - Unlocking Energy Efficiency
25-in-5 - Unlocking Energy Efficiency
 
Synopsis & toc global renewable energy 2009 - 2018
Synopsis & toc global renewable energy 2009 - 2018Synopsis & toc global renewable energy 2009 - 2018
Synopsis & toc global renewable energy 2009 - 2018
 
Coalition Climate Policy and the National Climate Interest
Coalition Climate Policy and the National Climate InterestCoalition Climate Policy and the National Climate Interest
Coalition Climate Policy and the National Climate Interest
 
Slideshare -energy_prices_explained_what_are_feed-in_tariffs_and_the_renewab...
Slideshare  -energy_prices_explained_what_are_feed-in_tariffs_and_the_renewab...Slideshare  -energy_prices_explained_what_are_feed-in_tariffs_and_the_renewab...
Slideshare -energy_prices_explained_what_are_feed-in_tariffs_and_the_renewab...
 
Carsten Rolle, Executive Director WEC Germany
Carsten Rolle, Executive Director WEC Germany Carsten Rolle, Executive Director WEC Germany
Carsten Rolle, Executive Director WEC Germany
 
Low carbon Finland 2050. VTT clean energy technology strategies for society
Low carbon Finland 2050. VTT clean energy technology strategies for societyLow carbon Finland 2050. VTT clean energy technology strategies for society
Low carbon Finland 2050. VTT clean energy technology strategies for society
 
VTT Visions: Low Carbon Finland 2050
VTT Visions: Low Carbon Finland 2050VTT Visions: Low Carbon Finland 2050
VTT Visions: Low Carbon Finland 2050
 

Similar to (electronic version)Effects of an Energy Policy in the Industrial Sector The Australian Market Case

SBC Carbon Price 2011 07 28
SBC Carbon Price 2011 07 28SBC Carbon Price 2011 07 28
SBC Carbon Price 2011 07 28Barbara Albert
 
Energy policy aus
Energy policy ausEnergy policy aus
Energy policy ausRohil Kumar
 
Australian_Cost_Curve_for_GHG_Reduction
Australian_Cost_Curve_for_GHG_ReductionAustralian_Cost_Curve_for_GHG_Reduction
Australian_Cost_Curve_for_GHG_ReductionJames Slezak
 
26. TCI Cost of Living Spotlight Report 2011
26. TCI Cost of Living Spotlight Report 201126. TCI Cost of Living Spotlight Report 2011
26. TCI Cost of Living Spotlight Report 2011Richard Plumpton
 
Benefits of Putting Carbon Tax in Ohio State 12Benefits.docx
Benefits of Putting Carbon Tax in Ohio State 12Benefits.docxBenefits of Putting Carbon Tax in Ohio State 12Benefits.docx
Benefits of Putting Carbon Tax in Ohio State 12Benefits.docxAASTHA76
 
Energy Efficiency in Energy Legislation, Waxman-Markey, and Stimulus: Update ...
Energy Efficiency in Energy Legislation, Waxman-Markey, and Stimulus:Update ...Energy Efficiency in Energy Legislation, Waxman-Markey, and Stimulus:Update ...
Energy Efficiency in Energy Legislation, Waxman-Markey, and Stimulus: Update ...Alliance To Save Energy
 
Emission Statement - Issue 4 - Application and Technology Plan
Emission Statement - Issue 4 - Application and Technology PlanEmission Statement - Issue 4 - Application and Technology Plan
Emission Statement - Issue 4 - Application and Technology PlanGrant Budge
 
Clean energy regulation in Australia
Clean energy regulation in AustraliaClean energy regulation in Australia
Clean energy regulation in AustraliaGlobalRoadTechnology1
 
LEAKED: Energy Saving Trust FIT review fact sheet
LEAKED: Energy Saving Trust FIT review fact sheetLEAKED: Energy Saving Trust FIT review fact sheet
LEAKED: Energy Saving Trust FIT review fact sheetwjafrazer
 
Australian Energy Efficiency and Demand Side Management Activities
Australian Energy Efficiency and Demand Side Management ActivitiesAustralian Energy Efficiency and Demand Side Management Activities
Australian Energy Efficiency and Demand Side Management ActivitiesIEA DSM Implementing Agreement (IA)
 
Factsheet: Australian Government Action on Climate Change
Factsheet: Australian Government Action on Climate ChangeFactsheet: Australian Government Action on Climate Change
Factsheet: Australian Government Action on Climate ChangeTurlough Guerin GAICD FGIA
 
Climate Policy Webinar: Prospects for 2010
Climate Policy Webinar: Prospects for 2010Climate Policy Webinar: Prospects for 2010
Climate Policy Webinar: Prospects for 2010Alliance To Save Energy
 
MBI in china and brazil
MBI in china and brazilMBI in china and brazil
MBI in china and brazilPrince Gupta
 
Modelling the costs and benefits of clean air policy scenarios for residentia...
Modelling the costs and benefits of clean air policy scenarios for residentia...Modelling the costs and benefits of clean air policy scenarios for residentia...
Modelling the costs and benefits of clean air policy scenarios for residentia...Environmental Protection Agency, Ireland
 
Chapter 13: UK Renewable Energy Policy since Privatization
Chapter 13: UK Renewable Energy Policy since PrivatizationChapter 13: UK Renewable Energy Policy since Privatization
Chapter 13: UK Renewable Energy Policy since PrivatizationElectricidad Verde
 

Similar to (electronic version)Effects of an Energy Policy in the Industrial Sector The Australian Market Case (20)

POST-PN-403
POST-PN-403POST-PN-403
POST-PN-403
 
SBC Carbon Price 2011 07 28
SBC Carbon Price 2011 07 28SBC Carbon Price 2011 07 28
SBC Carbon Price 2011 07 28
 
Energy policy aus
Energy policy ausEnergy policy aus
Energy policy aus
 
20120130406012
2012013040601220120130406012
20120130406012
 
Australian_Cost_Curve_for_GHG_Reduction
Australian_Cost_Curve_for_GHG_ReductionAustralian_Cost_Curve_for_GHG_Reduction
Australian_Cost_Curve_for_GHG_Reduction
 
26. TCI Cost of Living Spotlight Report 2011
26. TCI Cost of Living Spotlight Report 201126. TCI Cost of Living Spotlight Report 2011
26. TCI Cost of Living Spotlight Report 2011
 
Climate Adaptation
Climate AdaptationClimate Adaptation
Climate Adaptation
 
Benefits of Putting Carbon Tax in Ohio State 12Benefits.docx
Benefits of Putting Carbon Tax in Ohio State 12Benefits.docxBenefits of Putting Carbon Tax in Ohio State 12Benefits.docx
Benefits of Putting Carbon Tax in Ohio State 12Benefits.docx
 
Energy Efficiency in Energy Legislation, Waxman-Markey, and Stimulus: Update ...
Energy Efficiency in Energy Legislation, Waxman-Markey, and Stimulus:Update ...Energy Efficiency in Energy Legislation, Waxman-Markey, and Stimulus:Update ...
Energy Efficiency in Energy Legislation, Waxman-Markey, and Stimulus: Update ...
 
Emission Statement - Issue 4 - Application and Technology Plan
Emission Statement - Issue 4 - Application and Technology PlanEmission Statement - Issue 4 - Application and Technology Plan
Emission Statement - Issue 4 - Application and Technology Plan
 
Clean energy regulation in Australia
Clean energy regulation in AustraliaClean energy regulation in Australia
Clean energy regulation in Australia
 
LEAKED: Energy Saving Trust FIT review fact sheet
LEAKED: Energy Saving Trust FIT review fact sheetLEAKED: Energy Saving Trust FIT review fact sheet
LEAKED: Energy Saving Trust FIT review fact sheet
 
Presentation1
Presentation1Presentation1
Presentation1
 
Australian Energy Efficiency and Demand Side Management Activities
Australian Energy Efficiency and Demand Side Management ActivitiesAustralian Energy Efficiency and Demand Side Management Activities
Australian Energy Efficiency and Demand Side Management Activities
 
UKERC Review of UK Energy Policy
UKERC Review of UK Energy PolicyUKERC Review of UK Energy Policy
UKERC Review of UK Energy Policy
 
Factsheet: Australian Government Action on Climate Change
Factsheet: Australian Government Action on Climate ChangeFactsheet: Australian Government Action on Climate Change
Factsheet: Australian Government Action on Climate Change
 
Climate Policy Webinar: Prospects for 2010
Climate Policy Webinar: Prospects for 2010Climate Policy Webinar: Prospects for 2010
Climate Policy Webinar: Prospects for 2010
 
MBI in china and brazil
MBI in china and brazilMBI in china and brazil
MBI in china and brazil
 
Modelling the costs and benefits of clean air policy scenarios for residentia...
Modelling the costs and benefits of clean air policy scenarios for residentia...Modelling the costs and benefits of clean air policy scenarios for residentia...
Modelling the costs and benefits of clean air policy scenarios for residentia...
 
Chapter 13: UK Renewable Energy Policy since Privatization
Chapter 13: UK Renewable Energy Policy since PrivatizationChapter 13: UK Renewable Energy Policy since Privatization
Chapter 13: UK Renewable Energy Policy since Privatization
 

(electronic version)Effects of an Energy Policy in the Industrial Sector The Australian Market Case

  • 1. Effects of an Energy Policy in the Industrial Sector The Australian Market Case Selma Dogic, Meihua Huang, Mianfeng Liu, Syed N. Miah, Qinpeng Wang, Michael S. Williams, and Yang Yang Department of Economics, Georgia Institute of Technology December 02, 2014 Abstract This paper aims to depict the market for electricity in the industrial sector of Australia and to show the impacts that a government intervention would have. Specifically, this paper investigates the effectiveness of the Australia Clean Energy Act of 2011 by examining the industry response in regard to the demand of electricity and the output of goods. Keywords: Energy market, energy intensive industries, industrial energy demand JEL Codes: D00, D4, Q4
  • 2. 1 Introduction This paper aims to depict the market for energy in the industrial sector of Australia and to show the impact that a government intervention would have. Specifically, this paper investigates the effectiveness of Australia’s Clean Energy Act of 2011 by examining the tax policy, as well as its repeal, and understanding industry’s response in regards to its demand of energy and its output of goods. The results from this research will better inform the role that governments should or should not play in markets and it will give greater insight into the US’s Clean Air Act, a policy similar to the Australian Clean Energy Act. In particular, the Environmental Protection Agency (EPA), following President Obama’s directive, will set flexible carbon pollution standards, regulations or guidelines, as appropriate, for new power plants, modified and reconstructed power plants, and existing power plants under Section 111 of the Clean Air Act (EPA, 2014). This research will cast new light on the costs and benefits of the performance standards and regulations underway in the US. 1.1 Policy History and Framework In 2011 the Australian government proposed a Clean Energy Plan that aimed to reduce carbon emissions, encouraging energy efficiency, and increasing the use of clean energy. The Plan was designed to reduce greenhouse gas emissions by 5% by 2020 (compared to 2000 levels) and by 80% by 2050 (Parliament, A., 2011). However, these aggressive targets do not strictly refer to domestic reductions. It is estimated that Australia will have to rely 1
  • 3. on purchasing permits from other countries to meet this overall target. To be more specific, eventually 55% of Australian tax dollars are paying firms from the rest of the world to reduce their emissions (Robson, 2013). Related legislation in the Clean Energy Act of 2011 introduced a carbon pricing mechanism in two phases. The first phase implemented permits on emissions with no cap; in essence these permits acted much like a carbon tax that put a price on Australia’s carbon pollution. This was applied to Australia’s largest carbon emitters (also called liable entities). Under the carbon pricing mechanism, an entity was liable if it was responsible for one or more facilities that emitted a covered scope of one emission of 25,000 tons of carbon dioxide equivalent (CO2e) or more in an eligible financial year. For each of these financial years, liable entities had to surrender one eligible emissions unit for every ton of CO2e that they produced. Entities would have the opportunity to acquire eligible emissions units by purchasing carbon units at a fixed price ($23 per unit in 2012-2013, $24.15 in 2013-2014) from the Clean Energy Regulator or through the creation of eligible Australian Carbon Credit Units (ACCUs) through the Carbon Farming Initiative with emission avoidance activities. The emission avoidance activities included storing carbon in living biomass, dead organic matter or soil. As a context of the fixed price mechanism, the EU price as of August 9th, 2013 was €4.48, or $6.50, which is roughly 27% of the carbon tax in Australia in 2013. 2
  • 4. Entities could also purchase carbon units and eligible ACCUs in the secondary market from others who held such units (the use of international permits to meet the requirement was not allowed during the fixed price period); or with industry assistance from the Jobs and Competitiveness Program. The Jobs and Competitiveness Program was aimed at providing assistance to entities that were conducting emissions-intensive and trade-exposed activities (EITE) such that they faced high carbon costs but were unable to pass these costs to global markets. The most EITE activities, such as aluminum production, steel manufacturing, pulp and paper manufacturing, glass making, cement production and petroleum refining, would receive assistance to cover 94.5% of industry average carbon costs in the first year of the carbon price, with less EITE activities to receive assistance to cover 66% of industry average carbon costs (Clean Energy Regulator, 2013). Eventually, if a liable entity did not surrender any or enough units, it would be liable for a “unit shortfall charge” at 130% of the price for the relevant financial year multiplied by the number of shortfall units. The carbon pricing mechanism covered a range of large businesses and industrial facilities (around 370 businesses) which were responsible for approximately 60% of Australia’s carbon emissions. Generally, smaller businesses or households would not be affected. Under the initial policy design, the second phase was to be implemented in 2015 with a flexible price or cap and trade scheme. However, the carbon pricing mechanism had been abolished in July of 2014 with the repeal of the Clean Energy Act of 2011. 3
  • 5. 1.2 Costs and Benefits of the Policy Expected pros and cons of the policy before implementation are summarized as follows: ● The carbon tax will incentivize the industry to reduce emissions. It was expected that emissions in the electricity sector would decrease right after the introduction of the carbon tax. According to Australia’s national greenhouse accounts published by the Australian Department of the Environment, emissions from the electricity sector have been falling since 2008/2009, when electricity emissions fell by nearly 12% mainly due to the reduction of demand and rise of retail electricity price. With the introduction of the carbon tax, the price of an electricity input (such as black coal) is expected to rise. From a standard producer theory, in the long run, the electricity producer may switch to alternative inputs with lower emissions such as hydrogen engines or solar power, and the tax will reduce consumer demand as electricity becomes less affordable. However, the effect on overall emissions is not as strong as indicated by Robson (2013). In his paper, Robson wrote that the carbon tax will lead to the reduction of domestic emissions levels below projected “business as usual” cases, but not the absolute level, which is not expected to fall until 2043. The figure below depicts Australia’s energy consumption by fuel type between the years of 2010 and 2013. Between the years of 2011/2012 and 2012/2013 Australia’s consumption of renewable energy grew by 11.5% while its consumption of coal decreased by almost 6%. 4
  • 6. Figure 1. Australian Energy Consumption by Fuel Type (BREE, 2014) ● The carbon tax will help raise revenue for the government. The revenue raised could be used to reduce income tax (by increasing the tax-free threshold). It could also increase pensions and welfare payments to cover expected price increases; the new tax revenue could be used to introduce compensation for some affected industries and repair the damage caused by environmental pollution. ● The carbon tax will lead to a socially efficient outcome by removing negative externalities. Carbon pollution is a negative externality, which imposes a cost for the whole society instead of the consumer alone. It is postulated that the emissions intensive industries will create excessive carbon pollutions as negative externalities. 5
  • 7. Therefore, the tax is a means to internalize the externality such that those who cause environmental cost are made to pay the full social cost of their actions. With the tax introduced as the external cost, demand will fall and the new equilibrium will be socially efficient. ● The optimal level of carbon tax cannot be known in advance without several rounds of changes, making it politically vulnerable. Robson (2013) points out that internationally, the cap and trade scheme is more popular. Although the carbon tax policy with perfect information can lead to the same outcome as a cap and trade scheme, in reality, the perfect information assumption is shaky. A carbon tax is preferred in circumstances where the marginal benefit curve is relatively flat and the marginal cost curve is relatively steep, which may not be the case, argued by Robson (2013). ● The carbon tax will have economic and fiscal effects on Australian economy. The carbon tax may have macroeconomic outcomes such as GDP losses and unemployment. A number of researchers are supporting this argument. For instance, McKibbin et al (2010) evaluated the costs of commitments under the Copenhagen for Australia: the GDP loss in 2020 is estimated to be -6.3%. In addition, Siriwardana et al (2011) projects a 0.75% rise in the consumer price index and a -0.68% decrease in GDP as affected by the carbon tax policy. Siriwardana et al (2011) also estimated that the price of electricity will rise by about 26% in the short run and by 43% above business as usual by the Australian government model. 6
  • 8. Finally, the government expects the relative reduction in real wages compared to baseline to be much steeper than the overall reduction in GDP, which will cause job losses in certain sectors. ● The carbon tax will likely result in the shift of production to nations without the tax or where the tax is low. This defeats the purpose of cutting carbon emissions as a global joint effort. 1.3 Impact The true economic consequences of the legislation can be examined by observing its impact on specific segments of the economy. Initial projections suggested that the legislation would have a modest overall effect on most aggregate economic variables. However, belying the negligible projected impacts on real GDP and inflation were significant actual or realized effects that were detrimental to specific industries and groups within the economy. The majority of the 75,000 businesses liable to pay the tax did not meet the requirements of the Jobs and Competitiveness Program. That is, they were not EITE entities and, therefore, did not receive assistance to help absorb the higher carbon costs. Among such firms, industry surveys that included the service, manufacturing and construction industries suggest that firms in less competitive markets had a greater tendency to pass on higher energy input costs to consumers (smaller businesses and households). In contrast, firms in more competitive markets were more likely to incur the higher costs and accept lower profits. In some cases - particularly in industries reliant on energy such as food 7
  • 9. processing, plastics and chemicals, metal manufacturing and oil refining - there has been a marked reduction in planned investment and even some relocation of production facilities offshore. While higher energy bills (namely electricity and gas) were the chief cost-related difficulties faced by firms, the tax also added to rising packaging, transport and other expenses that involve the use of non-renewable energy. This coincided with the largest price increase for electricity and gas in Australia since the early 1980s (Ai Group, 2013). The Clean Energy Act was designed to raise producers' costs, leading to higher output prices faced by businesses and consumers who would then be compensated by the government. Half of all businesses surveyed six months after the implementation of the tax reported higher input costs (to which electricity costs were a major contributor). From the policymakers’ perspective, the problem was that in many sectors the anticipated increase in output prices did not occur broadly. As mentioned above, there has been a clear relationship between competition and price changes in response to the policy: the more elastic the demand for output in a given market (with respect to output price), the less likely firms in that market were to pass on higher input costs to the consumer. For example, while the overwhelming majority of firms in the highly competitive food manufacturing industry reported input price increases, only a tenth of those firms raised their prices. Meanwhile firms enjoying low demand elasticities such as producers of pharmaceutical products and transport equipment were able to raise prices proportionally. Trade-exposed industries, which by definition face regional and global competition, were 8
  • 10. also found to have difficulties in passing through higher input costs. Service firms, which make up the largest component of Australia's GDP composition and are less trade-exposed, appear to have had greater price pass-through ability, accordingly. What emerges from considering the micro-level effects of the tax is that there were groups that benefited from the policy and those that were adversely affected. Firms with pricing power or full compensation for the cost of the permits had a means of capturing additional profits. Similarly, businesses that had low carbon output relative to competitors had a way to undercut competitors' prices. Corporate services firms such as accounting and consulting businesses also received some demand-side assistance from the tax because of businesses seeking advice on absorbing high energy costs. In contrast, power sector firms (excluding renewable energy producers) were directly harmed by the tax. Liable entities that did not receive full compensation - especially those in more competitive markets - faced higher carbon costs as well. Finally, consumers also bore some of the cost burden, mostly in the form of higher electricity prices. 9
  • 11. Figure 2. Electricity spot prices: weekly volume weighted average spot prices (AER, 2014) While the sector-specific effects are somewhat clear, the broader level trends in the economy have yielded less information about the policy's impacts. The policy's implementation has coincided with unfavorable movements in key economic variables. For example, unemployment began to steadily increase after the July 2012 implementation of the tax despite falling for 11 of the 12 previous quarters. Total job losses also began a steady rise. In the year following the tax's introduction, GDP growth declined from 3.6% to 10
  • 12. 2.4% (OECD, 2014). But a precise relationship between macroeconomic variable movements and the policy cannot be established yet. The aforementioned events do not necessarily imply a causal relationship with the tax. In fact, the only events that can be directly traced to the policy are increased electricity prices and a mild contribution to inflation. Even employment movements that were sharper than the average across all industries such as the 29% decline in mining employment from August 2013 to one year onward are better explained by other factors such as falling commodity prices (Bruce Einhom, 2014). This could be interpreted as meaning that the policy did not harm the economy. But as evidenced by its impact on competitive firm profits and consumer welfare, there were clear detrimental effects on certain actors within the economy. Moreover, this can alternatively be interpreted as evidence that the policy may not have adequately disincentivized carbon emission: If the effect of the carbon tax were strong enough to induce firms to change their production processes, then rises in the unemployment rate would be better explained by the increase in energy costs (assuming that firms would reduce employment in the short-run to respond to rising energy costs before implementing other cost-reduction measures such as switching to alternative energy sources). It is also of interest to consider that the electricity price increases that firms faced after July 2012 were driven by additional factors as well such as rising network costs. 11
  • 13. As initially expected, producers of alternative energies were among the beneficiaries of the policy. But a rapid shift in the sector’s outlook between enforcement and abandonment of the policy illustrate an important point. Total investment in the nation's renewable energy sector doubled in the first full year of the carbon tax (Giles Parkinson, 2014). Post-repeal, there was a steep drop off in such financing. Australia is now on track to record its lowest level of asset financing for large-scale renewables since 2002 in the current year. Each of the three largest firms investing in Australia's renewable energy sector have cited uncertainty about the current government's RET as the primary reason for the decline in investment. This highlights an important point to be observed: regardless of the pros and cons of environmental regulation, policy consistency is needed to fully determine whether it can be successful or not. The prospect and realization of higher energy prices, reduced investment and international competitiveness as well as spillover price increases in other energy-reliant markets produced a strong political opposition to the carbon tax. The legislation was also construed as favorable to firms with monopoly power. As a result, it was anticompetitive, according to this view. In addition, there was a perceived lack of balance with respect to responsibility and liability. While ten percent of the economy accounts for ninety percent of carbon pollution, the resulting higher energy prices and cost pressures affected a much larger proportion of the economy than the offending ten percent. Such a view does not, however, give consideration to the benefits gained from the carbon tax; for example, increased future 12
  • 14. living standards. These factors all contributed to the political developments that lead to repeal. 1.4 State of the Australian Economy If the Australian experience with environmentally-focused government intervention is seen as an experiment upon which other industrialized countries can base their policies, then the unique characteristics of the Australian economy should be accounted for before any generalizations can be made about the impact of such legislation. Since 1983, Australia has seen the floating of its currency to make exchange rates more flexible, transformation of the financial system through deregulation and substantial reduction of trade barriers such as import quotas and tariffs, among many other economically liberal changes to its economy. These reforms have made Australia the third freest economy in the world (The Heritage Foundation, 2014). Australia is one of the few industrialized countries that weathered the recent global recession without any significant slump in its economic performance. GDP growth rates progressively increased from 1.7% at the height of the global recession in mid-2009 to 3.7% in 2012 (The World Bank, n.d.). One of the key drivers of economic growth has been strong investment in the resource sector in response to what has been called "a mining boom". Over the last decade, investment in this segment of the economy has quadrupled while the capital stock has grown by 300% (The Commonwealth of Australia, 2013). This 13
  • 15. pouring of resources into resources has largely been the result of China's unprecedented growth over the same time period. In particular, there has been great demand for iron ore and coal, which are Australia's top export products. Iron ore is a key input in making the steel used for public infrastructure and housing projects while coal supplies the majority of China's energy consumption. With the country becoming Australia's biggest trade partner, investment in mining drove about half of GDP growth in 2011 (The Economist, 2012). In short, China's development has helped propel Australia's recent prosperity. In part for the same reason, the most recent growth projections for Australia have been dimmer than usual. China's growth rate is at the slowest pace since the global recession five years ago (The World Bank, n.d). The uncertainty surrounding China's economy, falling commodity prices and the increasing cost of doing business - partly because of regulatory burden (Productivity Commission, 2014) - has led to a decline in investment in the Australian resource sector. With mining and related sectors accounting for 19% of Gross Domestic Product (Tim Colebatch, 2012), investment in these sectors is an important part of the growth picture. Therefore, the reduced investment is expected to dampen economic growth in coming years and, indeed, there has already been a noticeable slow down (The Commonwealth of Australia, 2013; Hannam, 2014). 14
  • 16. Figure 3. Australian GDP growth (Reserve bank of Australia, 2014) At the same time, new drivers of growth are needed to strengthen growth prospects moving forward and lower the risk of eventually falling into a recession. The Government of Australia now expects the economy to transition from having its growth be based on resource sectors to growth based on non-resource sector output (The Commonwealth of Australia, 2013). However, this transition will be slow as non-resource based growth has 15
  • 17. been subdued. Even with resource sectors moving from the investment phase to the production phase and the exports coming out of those sectors expected to make a larger contribution to growth, production outside of resource sectors will need to expand to fill the void created by falling investment. Exports may also be constrained by a strong currency. While Australia's national debt is among the lowest in the developed world, its year-to-year budget position has diminished in recent years, with deficits expected every year up to 2024 without a policy change (The Commonwealth of Australia, 2013). Part of this deterioration is due to a weaker economic outlook and the resulting reduced public revenue. Future growth is expected to be led by growth outside of the mining and natural resource sectors and such growth has appeared to be sluggish. As a result, real GDP is forecast to grow at 2.5 % in 2014-15, compared to the 3 % estimate for 2013. According to the ruling Liberal government's estimates, the other reason for the weakening of the budget position is that expenditures are needed to address unresolved fiscal matters from the outgoing Labor party's administration of government. These include a grant to the Reserve Bank of Australia to help withstand shocks ($8.8 Billion) , providing additional funding for a policy relating to offshore processing of illegal maritime arrivals ($1.2 billion), restoring outlays for a fair funding agreement for Australian schools ($1.2 Billion) and following up on a backlog of announced but unlegislated tax and pension measures ($2.9 billion) (The Commonwealth of Australia, 2013). 16
  • 18. The factors mentioned up to this point provide some context for evaluating the impact of the carbon tax on the Australian economy. But the effect of the tax on macroeconomic variables should be considered alongside more sector-specific information to properly gauge what the true consequences of the policy are. A microeconomic accounting for the policy's impact revealed significant factors that were detrimental to specific industries and groups within the economy. Thus the Australian carbon tax should be viewed through the prism of an economy with a resource sector that is expected to slow down and is in need of non-resource drivers of growth, which signifies that the effect of the policy on individual groups and actors in the economy are of paramount importance. The weaker economic outlook given by government projections underscores the need to emphasize policies that improve productivity, allow firms to be more efficient and reduce the regulatory burden on businesses and individuals. Ending the carbon tax was expected to reduce cost pressures on households and businesses and is consistent with meeting these needs. Predictably, the Australian senate vote repealing the tax coincided with a surge in business confidence (National Australia Bank, 2014). The repeal has also been linked to above-average consumer optimism as reduced energy costs offset some of the concerns over stagnant wages, rising unemployment and high housing prices (National Australia Bank, 2014). Annual household savings produced by the repeal may vary between $250 and $550 per household. Much of these savings are on electricity costs. In addition, some firms that received full compensation from the government (essentially 17
  • 19. getting free pollution permits) were known to pass higher costs on to consumers regardless, keeping the difference as profit. The repeal has ended this practice. It seems clear that the carbon tax in Australia reshuffled economic welfare from certain groups to others. It likely affected business and consumer sentiment, which are important for the country's economic performance. But broad economy-wide impacts have not been attributed to the policy. Since the United States and Australian economies are structurally similar, this might have implications for what the consequences of environmental regulation could be in the United States. Australia serves as a reasonable test tube as long as some of the factors mentioned above are accounted for (e.g. the mining boom, growth spurred by China's development and the transition to non-resource drivers of growth). Assuming an identical policy in the US, analyzing its merits might be a matter of determining whether a rise in electricity costs for consumers and businesses is an acceptable price for achieving environmental objectives. 2 Models In order to investigate the Australian policy and its effect on industry, it is imperative to understand what role energy plays in the industrial sector. Energy is an important input to the production process; it plays a similar role to labor and capital. The industrial consumption of energy can be altered by either using an alternative energy source, using a more energy efficient model, or by changing the utilization of capital stock. Only the last 18
  • 20. option can be implemented in the short run, implying that in the short run in order for a firm to decrease its energy consumption it must decrease its production. Industrial demand for energy follows the fundamental relationship between price and quantity, as price of energy increases the demand for energy decreases (all else equal). Hill and Cao (2012) showed in their paper that the short run price elasticity for electricity is .24, showing that a 1% increase in the price of electricity leads to a .24% decrease in the demand for electricity (all else equal). The authors also showed that there is a positive relationship between gross value added (GVA) and the demand for electricity, which is a logical deduction because as firms produce more their demand for electricity rises. The associated effects of a change in electricity price give a clear indication of what the expected effects of the regulation of energy are. Supply and demand forces, including regulations, can be measured using price. Usually new regulations of any market will make prices rise and deregulation will make prices fall. An abrupt long-term change in the price trendline is a good indication that a change in regulation has been implemented. Wholesale market prices are the first-line indication of the effects of supply and demand forces, and the prices of the wholesale electricity markets of Australia are the prices of which this research will focus to examine the effects of regulation. 19
  • 21. 2.1 Data Collection The following empirical model will utilize Australian government published data. Energy consumption data were collected from the Bureau of Resources and Energy Economics Australian Energy Statistics publication. Electricity prices are sourced from the Australian Bureau of Statistics Producer Index Series. Output data was obtained from the Australian Bureau of Statistics National Accounts Branch publications. The research also defines energy intensive industries based on energy consumption data published by the Bureau of Resources and Energy Economics. This allows for further understanding of the impact on energy intensive sectors and the effectiveness of the Jobs and Competitiveness Program. 2.2 Empirical Models This paper uses three different models to measure the effectiveness of the Australian policy : time-series, simultaneous equations, and ANOVA. The ANOVA and time-series models were used to analyze the relationship between average electricity price and the carbon tax policy. The simultaneous models built the aggregate demand and supply and were utilized to demonstrate how the policy affect the manufacture industry market. 2.2.1 Time-series Model 2.2.1.1 Theortical Model This model utilizes a combined regression-time series model to investigate the relationship between electricity price and the carbon tax policy. The form of the model is 20
  • 22. pricet = c + dummy + vt vt ~ AMAR(p; q) 2.2.1.2 Estimated Model and Results In this model, price is the average electricity price from July 2011 to June 2013. As the carbon tax policy of Australia began July 1st, 2012 , the dummy was set to 1 after July 2012. The dummy was used as the only explanatory variable to determine whether it caused a change to the mean of the price. The result is as below: 21
  • 23. From the form, the final regression function is 2.2.1.3 Hypothesis Testing After doing several tests, it is clear that the regression model satisfied assumptions both in the linear regression part and the MA part. In the regression result, the p-value for the Dummy variable is 0.0001, showing that the carbon tax had a very significant effect to the electricity price. As t=4.94 and p¡=0.05 for the dummy variable, it is possible to conclude that the carbon tax policy made a significant effect to the electricity price. After the policy began, the average electricity price raised about $17.9 per megawatt hour. However, the success of the policy is ambiguous. If the demand elasticity of electricity is big enough, it will have a large positive effect to reduce the energy cost; but if the elasticity is considerably small, it will only cause consumers to pay more (subsequently reducing consumer surplus). In order to calculate elasticity, the demand function of electricity must be determined. 22
  • 25. 3. Q-statistics for vt: 2.2.2 Simultaneous Equations Model 2.2.2.1 Theoretical Models Simultaneous equations were used to build up a model regarding the aggregate demand and supply in order to estimate whether the policy’s effectiveness. To set up the model, the structural equations must first be designed. Secondly, the equation’s completeness must be ensured (the number of equations is equal to number of endogenous variables). Lastly, the structural equation parameters (depending on characteristics of the model) need to be estimated. These steps produce the aggregate demand and supply equations as below: qd = a0 + a1 pd + a2x1 + e1 qs = b0 + b1 ps + b2y1 + e2 where qd = qs is the equilibrium condition 24
  • 26. Here variable x1 is something that shifts the demand equation but does not shift the supply equation and variable y1 is something that shifts the supply holding demand constant. 2.2.2.2 Estimated Models In this section, manufacturing output (market supply) was used to estimate market demand and producer price index as price sold or purchased. Moreover, variable lelep is the variable that will shift the supply holding demand constant and variable lgdp is the variable that will shift the demand without shifting supply curve. Clearly, the endogenous variables are quantity and ppi, where variable quantity is on the left hand side of the equations and variable ppi is on the right hand side of the equations. The remainder of the variables are the exogenous ones. The simultaneous equations models are as below: Demand : quantityd = a0 + a1 ppi + a2 lgdp + a3 quantity2 + e1 Supply : quantitys = b0 + b1 ppi + b2 lelep + e2 where variable quantitys(quantityd ) = Manufacture Sector Supply(Demand) variable quantity2 = Manufacture Sector Input variable ppi = Producer Price Index variable lelep = log of Average Electricity Price variable lgdp = log of GDP 25
  • 27. 2.2.2.3 Estimated Results Normally, OLS provides best linear unbiased estimators, but under the simultaneous equations model OLS is biased. Thus, the estimates from reg3 OLS option might be not good. One could use reg3 in Stata by using 2SLS, yielding consistent estimates for each just-identified or over-identified structural equation in a system. When using 2SLS, however, the structural parameters of each equation are estimated separately. Although the 2SLS estimator for each equation makes use of the information on all of the exogenous and pre-determined variables for the whole system, it ignores the information contained in the excluded endogenous variables in that equation and information contained in the error covariances. Therefore, 2SLS is not efficient, and thus 3SLS was used instead. Since the three stage least squares model is created by combining the 2SLS notion with SUR Model, iteration over the estimated disturbance covariance matrix and parameter estimates until the parameter estimates converge is preferred by most statisticians. Hence, the best results are expected to be generated by iterated 3SLS. After running the three stage least square regressions with different options (naive OLS, 2SLS, default 3SLS and iterated 3SLS) in Stata, a table with the comparison of the four different models is presented. Below are the best (iterated 3SLS) estimated demand and supply equations: Demand : quantityd = 172.20 - 0.03 ppi + 8.18 lgdp + 0.37 quantity2 + e1 Supply : quantitys = 62.30 + 0.04 ppi + 8.71 lelep + e2 26
  • 28. From the Stata output, the p-value for the equations are less than 0.0015. Additionally, the model offers other strong evidence: in the iterated 3SLS model, most of the coefficients are statistically significant at the 1% level and only the coefficient on ppi in the supply equation is slightly statistically significant, at the 10% level, and its p-value is approximately 0.086. Therefore, the results are very convincing that the carbon tax policy forced the whole manufacturing sector to produce less. After replacing the mean value for variable lgdp, lelep and quantity2, Stata generated the demand and supply curves. It is obvious to see that the manufacturing sector produced less after the government regulation was imposed, indicating that energy intensive industries consume a large proportion of energy for production. 27
  • 29. 2.2.2.4 Hypothesis Testing The basic assumptions such as nonsingularity , uncorrelated with the error term, the rank of the exdogenous variables and asymptotically convergent will hold if the stata doesn’t give us an error or warning. Since Stata generate the output for us, we assume these basic assumptions are satisfied. Another two important specification tests for simultaneous equations regression models are testing of exogeneity and testing of overidentifying restrictions. To test the the endogenity and whether the equations overidentify, Sargan’s (1958) statistic or Basmann’s (1960) statistic were used. Results are as below: By assuming ppi is also an endogenous variable, two unknowns exist in these equations, which are quantity and ppi. On the other hand, the test gives us Hansen-Sargan overidentification statistic, which rejects the null hypothesis that the model is overidentified. Therefore, the model meets expectations. 28
  • 30. 2.2.2.5 Interpretation and Intuition Is the carbon tax policy on manufacture sector really effective? Because variable quantity and ppi are measured by index numbers, it is known that the demand equation represents the demand elasticity of manufactured products. However, −0.03 is inelastic for the quantity demanded, signifying that however the price changes the demand for manufactured products, the effect is not large. And the quantity produced predicted by the models only decreases about 3%. Indeed, the model has room to improve due to the insufficient information. However, the conclusion is logical, because society is heavily reliant on these products (such as food and petroleum products). Clearly, further research needs to be conducted in order to explore the efficiency of the policy and its ability to reduce energy consumption without sacrificing social welfare. 29
  • 31. 2.2.3 Analysis of Variance Model This section investigates how government intervention through the implementation of a carbon tax impacts industrial output with seasonally adjusted GVA (gross value added) as an indicator. Quarterly GVA data from March 2010 to June 2014 were collected from the Australian Bureau of Statistics National Accounts Branch publications. Since it was 30
  • 32. postulated that the carbon tax policy directly impacts the electricity price while indirectly impacting the industrial output, average quarterly wholesale electricity prices were collected and studied jointly with the GVA data, which are shown below. A preliminary correlation analysis indicates a strong negative correlation (correlation coefficient -0.793) between the electricity price and manufacturing industry output, these results are expected. Figure 3 below depicts the electricity price against manufacturing industry output. A visual inspection reveals that the before and after electricity price and GVA seem to be clustered around different means, suggesting a drastic change incurred by implementing the carbon tax policy. Such a hypothesis leads to a k-means clustering analysis testing whether n observations could be partitioned into k clusters in which each observation belongs to the cluster with the nearest mean, serving as a prototype of the 31
  • 33. cluster. In this case, only two categories exist: pre- and post- intervention, making k equal to 2. The k-means clustering analysis leads to the following observations: 32
  • 34. 1. Pre- and post- intervention quarterly price and manufacturing GVA are clearly clustered around distinct centroids, indicating the policy intervention incurred a sharp change on electricity price and industry output. 2. The centroid GVA of manufacturing of metal products reduced from 4587 to 4328 million and the centroid electricity price increased from $30.1 to $55.3 per megawatt hour with the introduction of the policy. 2.2.3.1 ANOVA Model A similar approach is the ANOVA (analysis of variance). Considering the introduction of the carbon policy as a treatment, the pre- and post- intervention levels of quarterly manufacturing GVA reveal the effect of the treatment, which justifies the analysis of a one-way layout design of experiment. The model is as follows: yi j = hˆ + tˆ + ri j where hˆ is the grand mean, tˆ is the treatment effect, ri j is the residual. 33
  • 35. The null hypothesis that there is no treatment effect is rejected at the 5x10 -5 level, suggesting that the carbon tax policy has a significant negative impact on the output of the metal product manufacturing industry. 3 Discussion This research finds that the effects of Australia’s Clean Energy Act of 2011 are clearly measurable and significant. Using several variables, we analyze the time periods directly before and after the bill went into effect. By doing this, the immediate costs and benefits of the bill become obvious, and we find why the bill was shortly repealed. To the average consumer there was no benefit and only a cost. The only difference the average consumer could measure is an increase in the price of energy. The benefits, a healthier environment and sustained resources, would only be noticeable in the long run, and would be more difficult to quantify. The policy was implemented in order to reduce CO2e emissions and to encourage the use of alternative energy sources, a seemingly sound policy considering that Australia is the among the heaviest polluting nations in the world. In fact, according to the US Energy Information Administration, in 2011 Australia was the second largest per capita carbon dioxide emitter among the G20 nations. However, it is ambiguous whether or not the policy really targeted the nation’s heaviest polluters. The Jobs and Competitiveness Program 34
  • 36. offered assistance to entities that were emissions intensive in order to mitigate their higher carbon costs; the program aimed to help soothe the cost disruptions in the market but decreased the impact of the policy as the push to lower emissions and switch to alternative energies was weakened. It is also noteworthy that in 2013, coal was Australia’s second greatest export. Additionally, Australia’s other major exports were emissions intensive, signifying that the country had a comparative advantage in the production of emissions intensive goods and a relatively high opportunity cost of producing goods with low emissions. These factors caused the cost-burden of the tax to be relatively high to consumers. Although the industrial sector noticed an increase in the price of energy as well as a reduction in potential output, many firms were unable to pass along the costs. This was likely the cause of a competitive global market, which means that rather than a tax that led to a reduction of global emissions, the tax led to carbon leakage, thus defeating the purpose of the policy on a macro scale (Australian Government Department of Foreign Affairs and Trade; Robson, A. 2013). It is arguable that the timing of the bill could have been one of the causes of contention. Shortly after the worst recession since the Great Depression, the passage of a bill that raises energy prices at a rate more than three times that of the already-established EU rate is hard to economically justify, and part of the reason the act was abolished. Job loss increased and 35
  • 37. GDP growth declined during the 8 quarters that the carbon tax was in effect, something not yet precisely attributable to the carbon tax, but certainly politically so. 4 Conclusion The models used in this paper show that the policy had significant impacts in the industrial sector. Tests yield that the tax policy significantly impacted electricity prices. Yet, the effects of the rise in prices could have been offset by the demand elasticity for electricity. The policy caused a sharp reduction in the output of metal products as the policy caused electricity prices to rise. There is convincing evidence that the carbon tax caused the manufacturing industry to produce less. However, due to the nature of inelasticity, the effect of price on demand for manufactured goods is relatively small. In all, the ANOVA test was able to suggest that the policy had a significant effect to reduce metal product manufacturing output. It is also noteworthy that the policy faced harsh political opposition. Though a tax seems to be the most efficient form of an environmental regulation, and poses as a revenue to the government, it is impossible to determine the best rate in advance. This causes the tax to fluctuate early in its implementation and, due to its nature, the tax may appear to be unstable to the public and unpopular to many. 36
  • 38. Irrespective of the repeal of the tax in Australia, it serves as a tool for other nations considering similar policies. The greatest lesson to be learned is the impact of the costs to consumers and their perceived benefits. Nations wishing to implement environmental regulations of this kind must seriously consider the political repercussions as well as the economic costs. It has been shown that such a policy not only raises the prices of electricity, but also deeply disrupts the economy without benefiting the environment at a noticeable scale. Australia’s brief encounter with carbon emissions policy reform did not occur without political repercussions. A bill passed just two years earlier, then repealed due to negative coincidal events rather than amended, brings forth questions of whether the state was effectively governing. With that, some may find it the case that the government would have been more effective by simply lowering the carbon tax to a level more in tune with the proven-effective rates of the European Union. In any case, the Australia Clean Energy Act of 2011 was passed, then repealed, and there is much to be learned from the event by countries, such as the United States, that seek to pass similar legislation. 37
  • 39. References AER (2014). Industry statistics. [online: web] Viewed: 30 th October 2014. <http://www.aer.gov.au/Industry-information/industry-statistics> Ai group (2013). Ai Group Survey: business pricing responses to Australia’s carbon tax , the first six months. [online: web] Viewed: 23 nd September 2014. <http://www.aigroup.com.au/portal/binary/com.epicentric.contentmana gement.servlet.ContentDeliveryServlet/LIVE_CONTENT/Publications/Rep orts/2013/Carbon_price_impacts_Jan_2013_REPORT_FINAL.pdf> BREE (2014). 2014 Australian energy statistics data: Australian total net energy consumption, by state, by fuel, energy units. [online: web] Viewed: 1st December 2014. <http://www.bree.gov.au/publications/australian-energy-statistics/ 2014-australian-energy-statistics-data> Bruce Einhom (2014). Australian Economy Changes as Exports to China Slow. [online:web] Viewed: 25 th November 2014. <http://www.businessweek.com/articles/2014-09-25/australian-econo my-chages-as-commodity-exports-to-china-slow> Clean Energy Regulator (2013). Jobs and Competitiveness Program – guidance for applicants. V1.2_21/02/13. Australian Government.
  • 40. Giles Parkinson (2014). Is this the death of Australia’s renewable energy industry? [online: web] Viewed: 25 th November 2014. <http://reneweconomy.com.au/2014/is-this-the-death-of-australias-rene wable-energy-industry-83477> McKibbin, Warwick J, Adele Morris, and Peter J. Wilcoxen (2010). Comparing Climate Commitments: A Model-Based Analysis of the Copenhagen Accord. Discussion Paper 2010-35, Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard Project on International Climate Agreements, June 2010. National Australia Bank (2014). Monthly business survey. [online: web] Viewed: 10 th November 2014. <http://business.nab.com.au/wp-content/uploads/2014/08/monthly-bus iness-survey-july-2014.pdf> OECD (2014). Economics: Key Tables from OECD. [online: web] Viewed: 10 th November 2014. <http://www.oecd-ilibrary.org/economics/real-gross-domestic-product- forecasts_gdp-kusd-gr-table-en> Peter Hannam (2014). Who wins, who loses when the carbon tax goes? [online: web] Viewed: 10 th November, 2014. <http://www.smh.com.au/business/carbon-economy/who-wins-who-los es-when-the-carbon-tax-goes-20140709-zt1mm.html>
  • 41. Productivity Commission (2014). Relative Costs of Doing Business in Australia: Retail Trade. Research Report, Canberra. Reserve bank of Australia (2014). The Australian Economy and Financial Markets. [online: web] Viewed: 10 th November, 2014. <http://www.rba.gov.au/chart-pack/pdf/chart-pack.pdf> Robson. A. (2013). Australia’s carbon tax: an economic evaluation. Department of Accounting, Finance and Economics, Griffith University, Brisbane, Australia. Siriwardana, M., Meng, S., & McNeill, J. (2011). The impact of a carbon tax on the Australian economy: Results from a CGE model. Business, Economics and Public Policy Working Papers, 2. The Commonwealth of Australia (2013). Mid-year economic and fiscal outlook. [online: web] Viewed: 10 th November, 2014. <http://www.budget.gov.au/2013-14/content/myefo/download/2013_1 4_MYEFO.pdf> The Economist (2012). Australia’s two-track economy hitched to the China wagon. [online: web] Viewed: 10 th November, 2014. <http://www.economist.com/node/21560914> The Heritage Foundation (2014). 2014 index of Economic Freedom-- Australia. [online: web] Viewed: 10 th November, 2014.
  • 42. <http://www.heritage.org/index/country/australia> The World Bank (n.d.). GDP growth (annual %). [online: web] Viewed: 10 th November, 2014. <http://data.worldbank.org/indicator/NY.GDP.MKTP.KD.ZG> Tim Colebatch (2012). Our economic irrationalism. [online: web] Viewed: 8 th November, 2014. <http://www.smh.com.au/federal-politics/political-opinion/our-economi c-irrationalism-20120312-1uwde.html>