SlideShare a Scribd company logo
1 of 12
Download to read offline
Alberta’s	Environmental	Farm	Plan	
Policy	Review	
	
By:	Tyler	Kueber		
Submitted	to:	Green	Hectares	April	26,	2016
Introduction:		
	
The	global	agriculture	industry	faces	many	conflicting	ideologies	as	a	result	
of	two	competing	demands	imposed	on	agricultural	producers	and	policy	makers;	
the	 production	 of	 food	 for	 a	 growing	 population	 and	 the	 reduction	 of	 the	
environmental	 impacts	 associated	 with	 that	 production	 (Robertson	 and	 Swinton	
2005).	 Creating	 an	 effective	 policy	 to	 reduce	 agriculture	 pollution	 within	 Alberta	
presents	 many	 challenges	 due	 the	 diverse	 geological,	 political,	 and	 producer	
landscape	 resulting	 from	 contrasting	 productivism	 and	 environmentalism	 ideals.	
Pollution	generated	by	agricultural	activities	presents	many	challenges	because	it	
generally	 involves	 a	 large	 number	 of	 diffuse	 pollution	 sources.	 	 The	 abatement	
practices	associated	with	each	form	of	pollution	are	generally	unobservable	making	
it	 difficult	 to	 regulate	 agricultural	 pollution	 in	 an	 efficient,	 cost-effective	 manner	
(Weersink	et	al	1998).	Specific	pollution	sources	examined	in	this	brief	are	mainly	
crop	 inputs	 such	 as	 fertilizer	 and	 pesticide	 use.	 The	 agriculture	 input	 issues	
explored	 are	 not	 a	 comprehensive	 list	 of	 all	 environmental	 hazards	 created	 by	
agricultural	activities,	rather	a	focal	point	due	to	their	effect	on	tangible	issues	such	
as	 soil	 and	 water	 quality.	 Specifically	 in	 Alberta	 and	 western	 Canada,	 the	 spatial	
distribution	of	heterogeneous	agriculture	producers	across	a	large	geographic	area	
presents	 many	 additional	 challenges	 not	 only	 in	 the	 implementation	 of	
comprehensive,	effective	policy,	but	in	the	areas	of	monitoring	and	enforcement	of	
policy	initiatives.		
	
	Soil	 and	 water	 quality,	 climate	 change,	 and	 the	 loss	 of	 wildlife	 habitat	 are	
likely	 to	 grow	 with	 further	 globalization	 and	 increasing	 resource	 scarcity,	 thus	
defining	 the	 need	 for	 effective	 environmental	 policy	 (Miranowski	 and	 Carlson	
1993).	Successful	policy	must	be	targeted	at	effective	pollution	reduction	containing	
both	economic	and	environmental	dimensions	to	remediate	some	of	the	social	cost	
caused	by	agricultural	pollution.	
Environmental	Policy	Options:	
	
Weersink	et	al	(1998)	outlined	many	economic	instruments	policy	makers	
could	 utilize	 to	 achieve	 environmental	 objectives	 in	 agriculture.	 This	 study	
examined	the	ability	of	alternative	economic	instruments	to	achieve	environmental	
objectives.	The	study	presents	three	main	categories	of	instruments:	(i)	charges	on	
subsidies;	 (ii)	 tradeable	 permits;	 and	 decentralized	 policies.	 Whether	 these	
instruments	can	be	utilized	in	a	cost-effective	manner	depends	largely	on	the	ability	
of	the	regulator	to	monitor	and	enforce	the	choices	made	by	producers	(Weersink	et	
al,	 1998).	 Determining	 an	 effective	 environmental	 policy	 instrument	 targeted	 at	
reducing	 Alberta’s	 agriculture	 pollution	 ultimately	 depends	 on	 which	 conditions	
exist	among	the	agriculture	industry	provincially.	Charges	and	Subsidies	generally	
refer	 to	 an	 economic	 instrument	 (such	 as	 taxation)	 on	 emissions,	 ambient	
concentrations,	or	subsidies	provided	based	on	design-based	application.	In	order	
for	 these	 individual	 instruments	 to	 be	 enforceable	 and	 effective,	 several	 socio-
economic	conditions	must	exist	(summarized	in	table	1).
Table	 1.	 Conditions	 for	 economic	 instruments	 to	 be	 effective.	 Adapted	 from	
“Economic	 Instruments	 and	 Environmental	 Policy	 in	 Agriculture,”	 by	 Weersink,	 J.	
Livernois,	 J.E	 Shogren	 and	 J.S.	 Shortle,	 Canadian	 Public	 Policy,Vol.	 XXIV,	 p.	 314.	
Copyright	1998	by	JSTOR.		
Using	 a	 charge	 such	 as	 an	 emission	 tax	 or	 ambient	 fee,	 presents	 many	
problems	when	applied	to	the	agriculture	industry	because	the	conditions	for	the	
instrument	to	be	effective	are	not	met.	Some	of	these	conditions	include	the	inability	
to	 measure	 individual	 producer	 emissions	 at	 a	 reasonable	 cost.	 Since	 agriculture	
pollutants	are	generally	from	diffuse	source	occurring	over	a	longer	time	period,	an	
accurate	relationship	between	estimated	emissions	and	observable	inputs	is	poorly	
defined	 (Braden	 and	 Segerson	 1993).	 It	 would	 be	 difficult	 to	 effectively	 monitor	
resource	 quality	 over	 a	 large	 area	 such	 as	 Alberta	 due	 to	 the	 heterogeneous	
environment	conditions	(precipitation,	soil	type	etc)	and	its	influence	on	agronomic	
production.	 Therefore	 in	 order	 for	 a	 charge-based	 instrument	 to	 be	 accurate	 and	
effective,	the	input	tax	should	in	principle	vary	with	location	and	application	method	
(Zilberman,	 Khanna	 and	 Lipper	 1997).	 Due	 to	 the	 diffuse	 source	 nature	 of	
environmental	 pollution	 resulting	 from	 agriculture,	 if	 a	 charge	 is	 implemented,	 it	
must	 be	 addressed	 by	 preventing	 the	 generation	 of	 the	 residuals	 at	 their	 source.	
Most	other	environmental	policies	associated	with	point-source	problems	such	as	
those	 that	 exist	 in	 the	 energy	 industry	 attempt	 to	 control	 the	 delivery	 of	 the	
pollutant	between	its	source	and	final	delivery.	This	interception	strategy	cannot	be	
applied	to	the	agriculture	industry	(Weersink	et	al	1998).	Although	an	input	tax	may
reduce	input	use,	another	disadvantage	of	a	pure	tax	is	that	it	does	not	encourage	
any	other	abatement	actions.	These	actions	may	be	more	cost-efficient	options	such	
as	crop	choice	and	tillage	methods;	therefore,	the	most	cost-effective	attainment	of	
pollution	 is	 not	 always	 achieved	 through	 the	 use	 of	 a	 tax	 (Weersink	 et	 al	 1998).	
Further	to	this,	the	inelasticity	of	farm	input	demand	implies	charges	such	as	a	tax	
rate	 must	 be	 substantially	 high	 to	 induce	 the	 desired	 reduction	 in	 input	 use.	
Therefore,	it	is	unlikely	such	policy	is	politically	feasible	(Helfand	&	House	1995).	
The	 origin	 of	 non-point,	 diffuse	 source	 pollution	 is	 difficult	 to	 trace,	 therefore	 all	
policy	 options	 that	 require	 a	 monitoring	 or	 enforcing	 component	 are	 limited	 in	
feasibility	and	effectiveness.	
	
Instruments	such	as	tradable	permits	in	context	of	the	agriculture	industry	
could	be	based	on	inputs	such	as	fertilizer.	However,	since	pollution	derived	from	
fertilizer	 use	 is	 largely	 residual	 and	 heterogeneous	 in	 response	 to	 differing	
geological	areas,	agronomic	requirements,	size	of	farming	operations	and	the	effect	
on	 their	 respective	 environment,	 the	 relation	 between	 inputs	 and	 environmental	
problems	 lacks	 clear	 definition.	 Since	 individual	 firms	 specific	 contribution	 to	 an	
issue	such	as	surface	water	quality	is	difficult	to	accurately	quantify,	issuing	binding,	
effective	permits	would	be	difficult.	Though	capitalist	efficiencies	do	exist	in	terms	
of	 a	 firms	 decision	 about	 design	 and	 location	 of	 pollution	 control	 equipment	
(opposed	to	regulator	decision),	choosing	a	tax	rate	on	emissions	or	inputs	requires	
full	information	on	how	polluters	will	respond	to	the	charges.	This	information	is	
not	likely	known	by	the	polluters	themselves	in	the	short	run,	and	suggests	tax	rate	
structures	will	have	to	be	continually	revised	with	changes	in	economic	conditions	
(Weersink	et	al,	1998).	Further	to	this,	the	definition	of	a	polluter	would	have	to	be	
well-defined	 by	 a	 permit	 so	 that	 a	 sufficient	 market	 existed	 to	 make	 the	 permit	
actually	 tradable.	 As	 previously	 discussed,	 the	 heterogeneous	 composition	 of	
agriculture	 producers,	 various	 crop	 inputs,	 and	 geologic	 conditions	 prevent	 a	
standardized	definition	of	a	polluter.			
	
Decentralized	 policies	 such	 as	 liability	 rules,	 non-compliance	 fees,	
performance	bonds	and	property	rights	definitions	present	many	challenges	as	an	
economic	 instrument.	 Decentralized	 policies	 allow	 individuals	 to	 resolve	
environmental	 problems	 through	 the	 legal	 system	 or	 negotiations.	 Liability	 laws	
make	 polluters	 responsible	 for	 any	 damages	 they	 cause,	 while	 compliance	 fees	
target	individuals	polluting	above	an	ambient	standard	target.		Due	to	the	nature	of	
agriculture	 industry	 such	 as	 frequent	 pollution	 events,	 unclear	 cause	 and	 effect	
relationships	 involving	 many	 parties,	 and	 relatively	 unobservable	 actions	 of	 the	
polluter,	the	links	between	damage	and	causation	are	poorly	defined.	This	makes	a	
decentralized	policy	such	as	a	non-compliance	fee’s,	liability	laws	and	performance	
bonds	 also	 difficult	 to	 assess.	 Comparatively,	 in	 Alberta	 farmland	 is	 generally	 a	
privately	 owned	 resource	 where	 little	 market	 for	 ecosystem	 goods	 and	 services	
exists	to	the	producer.	Therefore	property	rights	definition	can	influence	whether	
the	producer	has	access	to	market	non-agriculture	goods	and	services	such	as	the	
hunting	of	wildlife.	If	property	rights	were	defined	to	include	wildlife	on	a	producers	
land,	a	market	may	exist	for	an	ecosystem	good	such	as	hunting	which	could	offset
the	 producers	 decline	 in	 agronomic-productivity	 for	 actions	 such	 as	 habitat	
preservation	(Weersink	et	al	1998).	
	
Moreover,	Weeersink	et	al	(1998)	suggests	rather	than	relying	on	the	best	
solution	 though	 economic	 instruments,	 the	 most	 effective	 way	 of	 dealing	 with	
diffuse	 source	 pollution	 in	 agriculture	 may	 be	 technological	 developments	 and	
business	 lead	 initiatives.	 Technological	 developments	 are	 generally	 correlated	 to	
business	 lead	 initiatives	 to	 provide	 producers	 with	 funding	 needed	 to	 adapt	
technology.	The	prominent	ideal	here	is	that	technological	advancements	focus	on	a	
more	accurate	and	efficient	utilization	of	inputs	such	as	fertilizers	and	pesticides.	
Through	more	efficient	use,	quantity	of	inputs	may	be	reduced	and	their	effect	on	
the	environment	minimized.	Policy	makers	generally	use	a	subsidy	mechanism	to	
encourage	 producers	 to	 adopt	 the	 most	 modern	 precision	 agriculture	 technology	
because	 adaptations	 are	 generally	 costly	 to	 implement.	 Like	 a	 tax,	 subsidies	 can	
occur	based	on	inputs	or	outputs	relative	to	production.	Several	disadvantages	of	a	
subsidy	 mechanism	 include	 cost-ineffectiveness,	 universal	 availability	 and	
inefficient	allocation	of	subsidy	funding	(Weersink	et	al	1998).			
Alberta’s	Environmental	Agriculture	Policy:	
	
Alberta’s	 Environmental	 Farm	 Plan	 is	 a	 policy	 that	 uses	 subsidy-based	
instruments	to	initiate	environmental	awareness	and	land	stewardship	through	the	
adoption	of	beneficial	management	practices	applicable	to	agriculture.	Awareness	
objectives	 are	 achieved	 through	 the	 producer	 documentation	 of	 environmental	
liabilities.	Alberta’s	Environmental	Farm	Plan	(EFP)	provides	producers	with	access	
to	subsidies	upon	proof	of	strategic	environmental	plans,	contained	in	a	document	
submitted	by	the	producer.	These	subsidies	provide	incentive	and	assist	producers	
in	 adopting	 strategies	 to	 mitigate	 the	 effects	 of	 agriculture	 production.	 Such	
mitigation	 strategies	 may	 include	 the	 adoption	 of	 precision-based	 technologies	
made	available	by	a	subsidy.	
By	 definition,	 Alberta’s	 EFP	 is	 a	 cross	 compliance	 policy.	 This	 refers	 to	 a	
program	 that	 ties	 eligibility	 for	 agricultural	 support	 to	 meeting	 a	 specific	
environmental	criterion.		
	
Farmer,	Rancher	and	Producer	Incentive:	
	
	 The	Environmental	Farm	Plan	(EFP)	is	a	voluntary,	whole	farm,	self-assessment	
tool	that	helps	producers	identify	their	environmental	risks	and	develop	plans	to	
mitigate	 identified	 risks.	 A	 diverse	 range	 of	 producers	 are	 attracted	 to	 the	
Environmental	Farm	Plan	(EFP)	program	because	it	helps	them	identify	and	address	
environmental	 risks	 in	 their	 respective	 operation,	 while	 increasing	 their	
understanding	 of	 legal	 requirements	 related	 to	 environmental	 issues.	
Protecting	water,	air	and	soil	quality	is	key	to	the	sustainable	production	of	crops	
and	livestock	thus	it	is	a	vested	interest	to	producers.	An	EFP	will	identify	what	a	
producer	 is	 already	 mitigating	 effectively	 and	 pinpoint	 where	 improvement	 in
environmental	hazard	mitigation	can	occur.	Many	producers	value	this	information	
because	 they	 are	 focused	 on	 leaving	 a	 farm	 legacy	 for	 future	 generations	 thus	
focusing	on	water,	air,	and	soil	quality	is	a	primary	objective.	By	addressing	some	of	
these	risks	in	an	EFP,	producers	may	additionally	increase	operational	efficiency	by	
reassessing	fertilizer	use	or	monitoring	of	fuel	storage	tanks	for	example.	
	
	 	Upon	completion	of	an	EFP,	many	farmers	and	ranchers	are	available	to	receive	
funding	to	aid	in	the	adoption	of	precision	agriculture	technologies	if	it	correlates	to	
one	 of	 the	 beneficial	 management	 practices	 stated	 in	 their	 EFP.	 Producers	 are	
attracted	to	precision	agriculture	technology	because	this	technology	can	increase	
the	 efficiency	 of	 machinery	 and	 input	 use.	 Precision	 agriculture	 can	 provide	
producers	 with	 an	 opportunity	 to	 simultaneously	 reduce	 environmental	 impacts	
while	improving	productivity	and	profits	on	the	farm	(Bongiovanni	and	Lowenberg-
DeBoer	2004).	Projects	available	for	funding	through	Growing	Forward	II	under	the	
EFP	 are	 quite	 comprehensive	 and	 include	 but	 are	 not	 limited	 to	 projects	 such	 as	
agriculture	 watershed	 enhancement,	 biosecurity,	 on-farm	 energy	 management,	
confined	 feeding	 operation	 stewardship	 etc.	 Further	 to	 this,	 the	 EFP	 promotes	
producers	 to	 pair	 environmental	 stewardship	 with	 agricultural	 production	 which	
can	be	used	in	the	marketing	of	agri-products.	Consumers	in	modern	day	Canadian	
society	are	increasingly	concerned	about	the	safety	and	quality	of	the	food	produced	
within	the	nation.		Sustainable	sourcing	is	becoming	a	requirement	of	many	major	
food	 purchasers,	 from	 manufacturers	 to	 restaurants.	 Thus,	 completing	 an	 EFP	
appeals	 to	 producers	 because	 it	 demonstrates	 to	 the	 public,	 government,	 and	
investors	that	farmers	and	ranchers	are	managing	their	environmental	risks.	This	
program	is	largely	voluntary,	thus	agriculture	producers	perceive	this	program	as	
attainable	 and	 viable.	 Producers	 adapting	 environmental	 hazard	 mitigation	
strategies	can	do	so	at	their	convenience	and	are	able	to	prioritize	tasks	based	on	
their	 specific	 operation.	 This	 flexibility	 and	 attainability	 is	 a	 crucial	 factor	
determining	 the	 success	 and	 adaptation	 of	 this	 provincial	 initiative.	 Since	 its	
inception	in	2003	the	Alberta	Environmental	Farm	Plan	has	had	8000	completed	
plans	which	represents	24%	of	Alberta	farms	and	just	under	two	million	acres	of	
agriculture	land	(Alberta	Environmental	Farm	Plan,	2016).		
	
Analysis	of	the	Environmental	Farm	Plan:		
	
One	of	the	main	incentives	for	producers	to	enrol	in	the	Environmental	Farm	
Plan	 is	 their	 access	 to	 funding	 which	 aids	 in	 the	 adaptation	 of	 new	 technologies	
possible	of	increasing	farm	operational	efficiency.	Determining	the	effectiveness	of	
precision	 based	 technologies	 can	 indicate	 the	 effectiveness	 of	 Alberta’s	 EFP	 at	
achieving	environmental	objectives.	
	
Schieffer	&	Dillon	(2015)	studied	several	precision	agriculture	technologies	
(auto-	steer	tractor,	variable	rate	nitrogen	application,	and	a	sprayer	with	automatic	
section	 control)	 and	 their	 affect	 on	 the	 economic,	 agronomic,	 and	 environmental	
performance	of	the	farms	in	their	study.	Additionally,	they	correlated	the	adoption
of	precision	agriculture	technologies	and	their	interactions	with	different	types	of	
agro-environmental	policies	(emission	limits	and	taxes)	and	the	change	in	relative	
effectiveness	of	those	policies.	Understanding	these	impacts	provides	insight	for	the	
effectiveness	 of	 Alberta’s	 Environmental	 Farm	 Plan	 in	 terms	 of	 its	 incentives	
(subsidies)	for	producers	to	adapt	the	same	precision	agricultural	technologies.		
Schieffer	&	Dillon	(2015)	suggest:	
	
“policy	failure	can	occur	when	such	policy	is	designed	for	traditional	
production	methods	and	fails	to	allow	for	the	changes	in	abatement	
costs	 associated	 with	 adoption	 of	 precision	 agriculture	 methods.	
Although	 incentive-based	 policies	 are	 often	 desirable	 for	 pursuing	
economic	 efficiency	 and	 cost-effectiveness	 when	 pollution	 sources	
have	 heterogeneous	 abatement	 costs,	 policies	 designed	 without	
information	about	the	technology	mix	used	by	farms	may	be	limited	in	
their	 effectiveness	 in	 reaching	 environmental	 goals.	 Quantity-based	
policies	(e.g.,	quotas)	may	be	more	robust	to	technological	change	or	
uncertainty	 in	 terms	 of	 achieving	 targeted	 environmental	
improvements.”			
	
Bongiovanni	 &	 Lowenburg	 (2004)	 also	 support	 this	 idea	 and	 suggest	 precision	
agriculture	 can	 lead	 to	 higher	 marginal	 abatement	 costs	 in	 the	 form	 of	 forgone	
profits,	 decreasing	 producers’	 responsiveness	 to	 those	 policies.	 Similarly,	 this	
analysis	suggests	that	Alberta’s	EFP	in	terms	of	promoting	the	adoption	of	precision	
methods,	may	be	ineffective	at	mitigating	environmental	hazards	with	this	incentive	
based	 mechanism	 alone.	 Assuming	 Alberta’s	 abatement	 costs	 are	 largely	
heterogeneous	due	to	the	geological	variation,	spatial	distribution,	and	production	
variations	across	the	province,	this	may	be	ineffective	at	actually	achieving	overall	
environmental	 improvements.	 Subsidies	 to	 support	 the	 adaptation	 of	 precision	
based	 technologies	 may	 be	 more	 effective	 at	 achieving	 environmental	
improvements	 in	 combination	 with	 input	 quantity-based	 limits	 or	 taxes	 on	
pollution.	 Problems	 with	 a	 subsidy-based	 instrument	 can	 be	 seen	 if	 we	 assume	
adoption	 of	 technology	 leads	 to	 an	 increase	 in	 use	 efficiencies	 of	 crop	 inputs	
perceived	by	all	producers.	This	adoption	of	this	technology	would	actually	make	
any	reduction	target	less	binding.	This	adoption	is	less	binding	because	the	farmer	
actually	needs	less	reduction	in	nitrogen	for	example,	in	order	to	meet	pre-existing	
reduction	 targets.	 Essentially	 the	 reduction	 of	 inputs	 gained	 by	 technological	
advances	is	offset	by	the	producers	continued	input	use	at	a	less	binding	level.	In	
this	 case,	 the	 marginal	 abatement	 cost	 of	 pollution	 is	 actually	 higher	 with	 the	
technological	adaptation,	so	the	producer	has	less	incentive	to	reduce	his	input	use	
further.	 Therefore,	 without	 an	 adaptable	 limit	 or	 tax	 that	 can	 be	 binding,	 the	
producer	has	no	incentive	to	further	reduce	pollution	caused	by	inputs.	Scheiffer	&	
Dillon	 (2015)	 explored	 the	 use	 of	 a	 tax	 and	 a	 limit	 as	 a	 policy	 instrument	 in	
combination	 with	 technology	 subsidy	 policy.	 	 With	 the	 adoption	 of	 multiple	
technologies,	 the	 tax	 policies	 were	 less	 effective	 than	 were	 the	 limit	 policies	 in	
reducing	environmental	impacts.	This	was	exhibited	by	the	larger	decrease	in	net	
return	for	tax	policies	and	the	greater	decrease	in	nitrogen	use	for	limit	policies	in
comparison	 to	 the	 adaptation	 of	 base	 technology	 individually	 (Scheiffer	 &	 Dillon,	
2015,	pg.	57).		
	
	In	 order	 to	 make	 Alberta’s	 EFP	 more	 effective	 at	 achieving	 pollution	
reduction	targets,	a	quantity-based	limit	would	be	the	most	beneficial	instrument.	
To	be	most	effective,	this	limit	would	have	to	correspond	with	the	specific	adopted	
technology	and	the	responding	effect	on	marginal	abatement	cost	(Scheiffer	&	Dillon	
2015).	 However,	 since	 this	 program	 is	 largely	 voluntary	 compliance,	 a	 quantity	
based	limit	would	have	to	be	a	provincial	mandate	spanning	all	industry	in	order	to	
ensure	 compliance	 of	 those	 participating	 in	 the	 EFP	 were	 not	 at	 a	 disadvantage.	
Extensive	 monitoring	 and	 enforcement	 efforts	 would	 be	 needed	 to	 ensure	 limit	
compliance	 across	 the	 province.	 The	 political	 and	 economic	 feasibility	 of	 these	
extensive	measures	poses	as	a	barrier	to	using	a	quantity-based	limit	to	increase	
policy	effectiveness.	
	
In	Alberta,	upon	adaptation	of	precision-based	technologies,	producers	have	
the	 opportunities	 to	 participate	 in	 the	 Agricultural	 Carbon	 Offsets	 Market.	 This	
carbon-offset	 market	 is	 a	 government	 incentive	 intended	 to	 further	 reduce	 the	
abatement	 cost	 of	 agricultural	 related	 pollution	 in	 terms	 of	 carbon	 emissions.	
Similar	to	the	EFP,	this	component	is	voluntary,	however	farmers	and	ranchers	do	
get	paid	for	their	efforts	to	reduce	emissions.	Although	this	has	moderate	financial	
rewards,	 it	 provides	 a	 new	 opportunity	 for	 income,	 one	 that	 has	 the	 potential	 to	
become	 a	 more	 developed	 market	 in	 the	 future.	 Though	 this	 incentive	 is	 not	
exclusive	 to	 the	 EFP,	 used	 in	 combination	 with	 the	 EFP	 may	 increase	 producer	
incentive	to	reduce	pollution	based	on	mitigation	strategies.	Moreover,	as	a	market	
for	 carbon-offsets	 is	 developed,	 this	 instrument	 may	 gain	 ground	 in	 terms	 of	
providing	 more	 incentives	 to	 producers	 resulting	 in	 greater	 adoption	 of	 carbon	
reduction	strategies.	
	
Schieffer	 &	 Dillon	 (2015)	 also	 suggests	 that	 the	 adoption	 of	 multiple	
technologies	 such	 as	 auto-	 steer	 tractor,	 variable	 rate	 nitrogen	 application,	 and	
automatic	 section	 control	 is	 more	 effective	 at	 achieving	 environmental	
improvements	than	adopting	one	technology	alone.	This	suggests	that	the	subsidies	
available	through	programs	such	as	Growing	Forward	II-upon	the	completion	of	an	
EFP,	may	be	more	effective	if	they	are	linked	to	multiple	adaptations.	However,	the	
cost	 of	 adopting	 multiple	 technologies	 ultimately	 places	 the	 burden	 on	 economic	
feasibility	 for	 the	 producer	 and	 the	 viability	 of	 their	 enterprise	 when	 it	 comes	 to	
implementing	these	changes.	One	could	suggest	a	solution	is	to	make	more	funding	
available	 through	 the	 subsidy	 framework	 such	 as	 Growing	 Forward	 II,	 but	 this	
ultimately	leads	to	the	issue	of	funding	for	the	subsidies;	who	is	paying	for	these	
subsidies,	and	if	the	investment	is	still	efficient	at	reducing	environmental	hazards	
at	this	new	cost.	This	point	is	supported	by	the	Weersink	et	al	(1998)	study,	which	
suggests	a	major	downfall	of	subsidy	policy	is	the	fact	that	is	it	incompatible	with	
debt	reduction-	a	major	goal	of	most	governments.	Moreover,	the	subsidy	incentives	
linked	 to	 Alberta’s	 Environmental	 Farm	 Plan	 are	 subject	 to	 the	 same	 criticisms	
discussed	by	Weersink	et	al	(1998);	greatest	pollution	contributors	may	not	apply
to	a	cost-sharing	program	if	the	incentive	is	insufficient;	funding	may	be	inefficiently	
allocated	in	terms	of	its	availability	to	non-polluting	firms;	and	inefficient	allocation	
of	funding	to	firms	that	would	have	adopted	the	abatement	regardless.	
An	additional	problem	with	Alberta’s	Environmental	Farm	Plan	is	the	lack	of	
enrolment	by	large	producers.	From	the	EFP	statistic	presented	in	the	introduction,	
the	average	size	of	farm	completing	a	plan	is	250	acres.	This	largely	suggests	that	
the	majority	of	large	farms,	or	corporate	farms	have	not	completed	an	EFP.	Lack	of	
enrollment	in	terms	of	large	commodity	producers	is	possibly	because	these	large	
producers	do	not	reap	the	same	rewards	as	other	smaller	producers.	This	could	be	
because	large-scale	producers	do	not	rely	as	heavily	on	subsidy	funding	available	
through	 programs	 such	 as	 Growing	 Forward	 II.	 One	 could	 argue	 that	 is	 policy	 is	
ineffective	 for	 larger,	 less	 financially	 constrained	 producers	 because	 the	 marginal	
cost	 of	 pollution	 abatement	 may	 higher	 to	 these	 producers	 than	 to	 smaller	
producers.	 An	 additional	 explanation	 could	 suggest	 that	 the	 benefits	 in	 reducing	
pollution	 residuals	 are	 difficult	 to	 assess,	 therefore	 large	 farms	 less	 reliant	 on	
funding	do	not	have	any	additional	incentives	to	promote	compliance	(Weersink	et	
al	 1998).	 Overall	 enrollment,	 specifically	 large	 farm	 enrollment,	 questions	 the	
effectiveness	 of	 the	 EFP	 to	 reduce	 diffuse	 point	 source	 pollution,	 as	 some	 of	 the	
largest	contributors	may	not	be	adapting	best	management	practices	or	mitigating	
environmental	hazards.	However,	if	these	practices	provide	economic	incentive	on	
their	 own,	 the	 producers	 may	 adapt	 them	 without	 enrolling	 in	 the	 EFP.	 In	 either	
regard,	lack	of	data	around	program	enrollment	and	technology	utilization	make	it	
difficult	 to	 assess	 the	 differing	 abatement	 costs	 perceived	 by	 the	 heterogeneous	
groups	 of	 producers.	 This	 knowledge	 gap	 limits	 the	 accuracy	 of	 instruments	 that	
could	be	employed	to	make	the	incentive	greater.	Overall,	the	effectiveness	of	this	
subsidy	incentive	depends	on	whether	it	is	fact	a	pollution-contributing	farmer	that	
is	enrolled	in	the	program,	and	the	magnitude	of	the	individual’s	pollution	reduction	
as	a	result	of	program	compliance.	
In	 the	 future,	 issues	 such	 as	 sustainable	 sourcing	 for	 agri-products	 are	
expected	to	be	increasingly	in	demand	in	the	marketplace.	Another	incentive	type	
mechanism	 employed	 by	 the	 EFP	 is	 the	 establishment	 of	 sustainable	 sourcing	
criteria.	 The	 Alberta	 Environmental	 Farm	 Plan	 in	 particular	 has	 partnered	 with	
Alberta	 Barley	 on	 a	 project	 to	 determine	 whether	 sustainable	 sourcing	 standards	
within	the	EFP	meet	global	standards.	Determination	of	these	standards	could	foster	
marketplace	 premiums	 for	 Canadian	 products	 produced	 under	 these	 conditions.	
Based	on	this	incentive,	the	EFP	holds	great	future	value	to	producers,	as	it	is	a	tool	
that	 can	 aid	 in	 achieving	 environmental	 objectives	 correlated	 with	 attaining	
sustainable	 sourcing	 status.	 Due	 to	 the	 relatively	 undefined	 existing	 standards	 in	
terms	 of	 global	 standards,	 the	 future	 effectiveness	 of	 this	 incentive	 is	 largely	
unknown	at	this	time.	
	
Additional	to	agriculture	input	use	and	sustainable	sourcing	guidelines,	the	
EFP	 recently	 added	 a	 new	 Species	 at	 Risk	 (SAR)	 component.	 This	 component	 is	
largely	based	around	promoting	habitat	conservation	for	species	at	risk	by	arming
producers	with	an	online	tool	to	identify	opportunities	to	conserve	those	species	at	
risk	 on	 their	 agricultural	 land.	 This	 implementation	 has	 incentive	 as	 it	 can	
potentially	 links	 to	 other	 issues	 such	 as	 sustainable	 sourcing	 status.	 Through	 the	
adaptation	of	the	SAR	component,	sustainable	sourcing	status	may	be	unattainable	
to	 the	 producer	 if	 species	 at	 risk	 are	 present	 on	 agricultural	 land.	 Producers	 are	
motivated	 by	 the	 market	 place	 advantage	 of	 labels	 such	 as	 sustainable	 sourcing,	
therefore	 habitat	 conservation	 may	 be	 a	 priority	 depending	 on	 the	 net	 gain	
perceived	by	the	producer	as	a	result	of	this	implementation.	Though	the	awareness	
of	conservation	ideals	for	species	at	risk	is	enhanced	with	this	component,	the	net	
gain	 to	 the	 producer	 will	 not	 be	 enough	 based	 on	 market	 place	 premiums	 alone.	
Furthermore	 this	 added	 component	 targets	 the	 potential	 for	 producer	
compensation	 in	 response	 to	 habitat	 conservation	 on	 agricultural	 lands.	 In	 other	
provinces,	 habitat	 conservation	 is	 currently	 funded	 by	 Environment	 and	 Climate	
Change	 Canada’s	 Species	 at	 Risk	 Partnerships	 on	 Agricultural	 Lands	 program.	
Though	in	effect	in	other	provinces,	the	effectiveness	of	this	instrument	in	Alberta	is	
questionable	because	other	decentralized-type	of	policies	already	exist	outside	the	
EFP	 framework.	 Other	 national	 initiatives	 such	 as	 the	 Ducks	 Unlimited	 program	
represent	pre-existing	decentralized	policies	in	terms	of	its	impact	to	property	right	
economics	 and	 habitat	 conservation.	 The	 Ducks	 Unlimited	 variation	 allows	 land	
owners	 to	 sell	 conservation	 easements	 against	 the	 title	 of	 the	 land	 in	 return	 for	
restricting	 land	 use	 to	 practices	 that	 would	 preserve	 habitat.	 Though	 Ducks	
Unlimited	primarily	corresponds	to	wetland	conservation,	other	initiatives	such	as	
Buck	for	Wildlife	are	already	in	existence.	In	order	for	this	component	to	be	more	
effective	 than	 the	 decentralized	 policies	 already	 in	 existence,	 more	 extensive	
compensation	 under	 this	 component	 will	 be	 needed	 in	 order	 to	 increased	
enrollment	if	that	is	the	policy	goal.	One	exception	to	this	could	be	species	that	are	
not	already	protected	under	the	Species	at	Risk	Act	and/or	species	not	targeted	by	
other	decentralized	policies.	In	this	case,	in	order	to	be	an	effective	instrument,	the	
SAR	 component	 included	 under	 the	 EFP	 would	 need	 to	 be	 more	 specialized	 and	
pertain	to	the	loopholes	that	other	decentralized	policies	do	not	already	address.	
Overall,	the	same	monitoring	and	enforcement	issues	that	reduce	the	Species	at	Risk	
Act	effectiveness	will	also	limit	the	effectiveness	of	this	EFP	component.	
	
Additional	 to	 promoting	 the	 most	 efficient	 technology	 and	 habitat	
conservation	 through	 incentives,	 another	 the	 main	 initiative	 within	 the	 EFP	 is	 to	
educate	 and	 increase	 awareness	 of	 environmental	 issues	 to	 the	 farming	 and	
ranching	 communities.	 Though	 education	 and	 awareness	 cannot	 be	 equated	 with	
quantifiable	 pollution	 reduction,	 its	 impacts	 on	 the	 producer	 ideals	 may	 provide	
ecological	 benefits	 that	 exist,	 however	 in	 a	 less	 tangible	 way.	 Through	 the	 use	 of	
education	 and	 awareness	 concepts,	 the	 EFP	 focuses	 on	 sustainability	 for	 future	
generations.	This	focus	on	future	generations	can	use	the	concept	of	moral	suasion	
to	 changing	 producer	 ideals	 of	 “good	 farming”.	 This	 can	 lead	 to	 a	 shift	 from	 the	
formerly	productivist	“good	farming”	ideals	to	more	sustainability	oriented	ideals	
(Burton	 and	 Paragahawewa,	 2011).	 Although	 difficult	 to	 assess,	 the	 increase	 of	
sustainability-focused	 ideals	 promoted	 by	 the	 EFP	 can	 lead	 to	 greater	 program	
compliance	through	adaptation	of	environmentally	friendly	practices.	In	turn,	this
creates	some	additional	value	for	Alberta’s	environmental	farm	plan	and	its	ability	
to	increase	land	stewardship	initiatives.	
	
	
Conclusion:	
	
Overall,	Alberta’s	Environmental	Farm	Plan	is	an	effective	policy	instrument	
to	 mitigate	 the	 effects	 of	 agricultural	 pollution.	 Though	 many	 criticisms	 of	 this	
incentive	based	policy	exist,	undoubtedly,	it	promotes	agricultural	land	stewardship	
while	 offering	 flexibility	 and	 attainability	 to	 foster	 producer	 appeal	 and	 political	
feasibility.	The	program’s	flexibility	extends	to	reach	Alberta’s	farming	and	ranching	
communities	so	that	the	Environmental	Farm	Plan	may	be	adopted	and	utilized	by	a	
wide	 range	 of	 producers	 with	 differing	 interests	 and	 ideals.	 Additional	 economic	
instruments	have	been	explored	to	increase	the	effectiveness	of	this	policy	such	as	
an	input	quantity-based	limit.	Many	issues	characteristic	of	the	agriculture	industry	
act	 as	 a	 barrier	 that	 prevents	 these	 economic	 instruments	 from	 being	 employed	
effectively.		
For	 those	 enrolled,	 Alberta’s	 Environmental	 Farm	 plan	 helps	 producers	
attain	greater	social	license.	Farmers	participating	in	the	Environmental	Farm	Plan	
are	proving	their	due	diligence	to	society	on	environmental	issues.	In	a	society	that	
increasingly	 demands	 more	 accountability	 from	 landowners,	 Alberta’s	
Environmental	Farm	Plan	is	a	framework	that	aids	agriculture	producers	in	their	
pursuit	of	becoming	efficient,	effective	and	responsible	stewards	of	the	land.
References	
Braden,	J.B.	and	K.	Segerson	(1993)."Information	Problems	in	the	Design	of	Nonpoint-Source	
Pollution	Policy,"	in	Theory,	Modeling	and	Experience	in	the	Management	of	Nonpoint-Source	
Pollution,	ed.	C.S.	Russell	and	J.F.	Shogren	(Boston:	Kluwer	Academic	Publishers).		
Bongiovanni,	R.,	&	Lowenberg-DeBoer,	J.	(2004).	“Precision	agriculture	and	sustainability.”	Precision	
Agriculture,	5(4),	359–387.		
Burton,	R.F.	and	Paragahawewa,	U.H.	(2011).	“Creating	culturally	sustainable	agri-environmental	
schemes.”	Journal	of	Rural	Studies,	27	(2011),	pp.	95–104.	
Helfand,	G.E.	and	B.W.	House	(1995).	"Regulating	Nonpoint	Source	Pollution	under	Heterogeneous	
Conditions,"	American	Journal	of	Agricultural	Economics	77(4):1024-32.		
Miranowski,	J.A.	and	G.A.	Carlson	(1993).	"Agricultural	Resource	Economics:	An	Overview,"	in	
Agricultural	and	Environmental	Resource	Economics,	ed.	G.A.	(New	York:	Oxford	University	
Press).		
Robertson,	G.	P.,	&	Swinton,	S.	(2005).	Reconciling	agricultural	productivity	and	environmental	
integrity:	a	grand	challenge	for	agriculture.	Frontiers	in	Ecology	and	the	Environment,	3(1),	
38–46.		
Schieffer,	J.,	&	Dillon,	C.	(2015).	“The	economic	and	environmental	impacts	of	precision	agriculture	
and	interactions	with	agro-environmental	policy.”	Precision	Agriculture,	16(1),	46-61.	
doi:10.1007/s11119-014-9382-5.	
Weersink,	A.,	Livernois,	J.,	Shogren,	J.	F.,	&	Shortle,	J.	S..	(1998).	“Economic	Instruments	and	
Environmental	Policy	in	Agriculture.”	Canadian	Public	Policy	/	Analyse	De	Politiques,	24(3),	
309–327.		
Zilberman,	D.,	M.	Khanna	and	L.	Lipper	(1997).	"Economics	of	New	Technologies	for	Sustainable	
Agriculture."	Australian	Journal	of	Agricultural	and	Resource	Economics	41(1):63-80.

More Related Content

What's hot

1.weather climate-crop yields
1.weather climate-crop yields1.weather climate-crop yields
1.weather climate-crop yieldsBMKG
 
Multivariate relationships influencing crop yields during the transition to o...
Multivariate relationships influencing crop yields during the transition to o...Multivariate relationships influencing crop yields during the transition to o...
Multivariate relationships influencing crop yields during the transition to o...Myers Shaiyen
 
Agriculture and the environment lessons learned from a decade of oecd work
Agriculture and the environment lessons learned from a decade of oecd workAgriculture and the environment lessons learned from a decade of oecd work
Agriculture and the environment lessons learned from a decade of oecd workDebbie-Ann Hall
 
7.4.2 Synergy between UNFCCC and UNCCD
7.4.2 Synergy between UNFCCC and UNCCD7.4.2 Synergy between UNFCCC and UNCCD
7.4.2 Synergy between UNFCCC and UNCCDNAP Events
 
Sustainable Landscapes: Food Security and adapting to climate change
Sustainable Landscapes: Food Security and adapting to climate changeSustainable Landscapes: Food Security and adapting to climate change
Sustainable Landscapes: Food Security and adapting to climate changeCIFOR-ICRAF
 
A synergy between the biophysical and the economic: the global market impacts...
A synergy between the biophysical and the economic: the global market impacts...A synergy between the biophysical and the economic: the global market impacts...
A synergy between the biophysical and the economic: the global market impacts...ExternalEvents
 
Supplementary guidelines: Addressing agriculture, forestry and fisheries in N...
Supplementary guidelines: Addressing agriculture, forestry and fisheries in N...Supplementary guidelines: Addressing agriculture, forestry and fisheries in N...
Supplementary guidelines: Addressing agriculture, forestry and fisheries in N...FAO
 
Assessing and reporting resilience of native vegetation using metrics of stru...
Assessing and reporting resilience of native vegetation using metrics of stru...Assessing and reporting resilience of native vegetation using metrics of stru...
Assessing and reporting resilience of native vegetation using metrics of stru...Richard Thackway
 
Climate change adaptation strategies of smallholder farmers the case of babil...
Climate change adaptation strategies of smallholder farmers the case of babil...Climate change adaptation strategies of smallholder farmers the case of babil...
Climate change adaptation strategies of smallholder farmers the case of babil...Alexander Decker
 
Item 11: Preparation of the Global Symposium on Soil Biodiversity (2020) - Mr...
Item 11: Preparation of the Global Symposium on Soil Biodiversity (2020) - Mr...Item 11: Preparation of the Global Symposium on Soil Biodiversity (2020) - Mr...
Item 11: Preparation of the Global Symposium on Soil Biodiversity (2020) - Mr...FAO
 
Tracking the Transformation of Vegetated Landscapes (VAST)
Tracking the Transformation of Vegetated Landscapes (VAST)Tracking the Transformation of Vegetated Landscapes (VAST)
Tracking the Transformation of Vegetated Landscapes (VAST)Richard Thackway
 
Experimental Design Thesis
Experimental Design ThesisExperimental Design Thesis
Experimental Design ThesisKaty Latico
 
Implementing Land Husbandry Best Management Practices in Hillside Areas
 Implementing Land Husbandry Best Management Practices in Hillside Areas  Implementing Land Husbandry Best Management Practices in Hillside Areas
Implementing Land Husbandry Best Management Practices in Hillside Areas ACDI/VOCA
 
Climate change preparedness and adaptation: a case of smallholder farmers in ...
Climate change preparedness and adaptation: a case of smallholder farmers in ...Climate change preparedness and adaptation: a case of smallholder farmers in ...
Climate change preparedness and adaptation: a case of smallholder farmers in ...Dr. Joshua Zake
 
Western Governors Drought/Wildfire Briefing
Western Governors  Drought/Wildfire BriefingWestern Governors  Drought/Wildfire Briefing
Western Governors Drought/Wildfire BriefingObama White House
 
The status and challenges of global soil fertility and the use of fertilizers
The status and challenges of global soil fertility and the use of fertilizersThe status and challenges of global soil fertility and the use of fertilizers
The status and challenges of global soil fertility and the use of fertilizersSoils FAO-GSP
 
Scaling up soil carbon enhancement contributing to mitigate climate change
Scaling up soil carbon enhancement contributing to mitigate climate changeScaling up soil carbon enhancement contributing to mitigate climate change
Scaling up soil carbon enhancement contributing to mitigate climate changeCIAT
 
Extension services strategies in adaptation to climate change in oyo state, n...
Extension services strategies in adaptation to climate change in oyo state, n...Extension services strategies in adaptation to climate change in oyo state, n...
Extension services strategies in adaptation to climate change in oyo state, n...Alexander Decker
 

What's hot (20)

1.weather climate-crop yields
1.weather climate-crop yields1.weather climate-crop yields
1.weather climate-crop yields
 
Multivariate relationships influencing crop yields during the transition to o...
Multivariate relationships influencing crop yields during the transition to o...Multivariate relationships influencing crop yields during the transition to o...
Multivariate relationships influencing crop yields during the transition to o...
 
Agriculture and the environment lessons learned from a decade of oecd work
Agriculture and the environment lessons learned from a decade of oecd workAgriculture and the environment lessons learned from a decade of oecd work
Agriculture and the environment lessons learned from a decade of oecd work
 
7.4.2 Synergy between UNFCCC and UNCCD
7.4.2 Synergy between UNFCCC and UNCCD7.4.2 Synergy between UNFCCC and UNCCD
7.4.2 Synergy between UNFCCC and UNCCD
 
Sustainable Landscapes: Food Security and adapting to climate change
Sustainable Landscapes: Food Security and adapting to climate changeSustainable Landscapes: Food Security and adapting to climate change
Sustainable Landscapes: Food Security and adapting to climate change
 
A synergy between the biophysical and the economic: the global market impacts...
A synergy between the biophysical and the economic: the global market impacts...A synergy between the biophysical and the economic: the global market impacts...
A synergy between the biophysical and the economic: the global market impacts...
 
Supplementary guidelines: Addressing agriculture, forestry and fisheries in N...
Supplementary guidelines: Addressing agriculture, forestry and fisheries in N...Supplementary guidelines: Addressing agriculture, forestry and fisheries in N...
Supplementary guidelines: Addressing agriculture, forestry and fisheries in N...
 
Assessing and reporting resilience of native vegetation using metrics of stru...
Assessing and reporting resilience of native vegetation using metrics of stru...Assessing and reporting resilience of native vegetation using metrics of stru...
Assessing and reporting resilience of native vegetation using metrics of stru...
 
Climate change adaptation strategies of smallholder farmers the case of babil...
Climate change adaptation strategies of smallholder farmers the case of babil...Climate change adaptation strategies of smallholder farmers the case of babil...
Climate change adaptation strategies of smallholder farmers the case of babil...
 
Item 11: Preparation of the Global Symposium on Soil Biodiversity (2020) - Mr...
Item 11: Preparation of the Global Symposium on Soil Biodiversity (2020) - Mr...Item 11: Preparation of the Global Symposium on Soil Biodiversity (2020) - Mr...
Item 11: Preparation of the Global Symposium on Soil Biodiversity (2020) - Mr...
 
Tree-Crop Interactions
Tree-Crop InteractionsTree-Crop Interactions
Tree-Crop Interactions
 
Tracking the Transformation of Vegetated Landscapes (VAST)
Tracking the Transformation of Vegetated Landscapes (VAST)Tracking the Transformation of Vegetated Landscapes (VAST)
Tracking the Transformation of Vegetated Landscapes (VAST)
 
Experimental Design Thesis
Experimental Design ThesisExperimental Design Thesis
Experimental Design Thesis
 
Implementing Land Husbandry Best Management Practices in Hillside Areas
 Implementing Land Husbandry Best Management Practices in Hillside Areas  Implementing Land Husbandry Best Management Practices in Hillside Areas
Implementing Land Husbandry Best Management Practices in Hillside Areas
 
Climate change preparedness and adaptation: a case of smallholder farmers in ...
Climate change preparedness and adaptation: a case of smallholder farmers in ...Climate change preparedness and adaptation: a case of smallholder farmers in ...
Climate change preparedness and adaptation: a case of smallholder farmers in ...
 
Western Governors Drought/Wildfire Briefing
Western Governors  Drought/Wildfire BriefingWestern Governors  Drought/Wildfire Briefing
Western Governors Drought/Wildfire Briefing
 
ISEERC97
ISEERC97ISEERC97
ISEERC97
 
The status and challenges of global soil fertility and the use of fertilizers
The status and challenges of global soil fertility and the use of fertilizersThe status and challenges of global soil fertility and the use of fertilizers
The status and challenges of global soil fertility and the use of fertilizers
 
Scaling up soil carbon enhancement contributing to mitigate climate change
Scaling up soil carbon enhancement contributing to mitigate climate changeScaling up soil carbon enhancement contributing to mitigate climate change
Scaling up soil carbon enhancement contributing to mitigate climate change
 
Extension services strategies in adaptation to climate change in oyo state, n...
Extension services strategies in adaptation to climate change in oyo state, n...Extension services strategies in adaptation to climate change in oyo state, n...
Extension services strategies in adaptation to climate change in oyo state, n...
 

Viewers also liked

Presentación Internet:ventajas e inconvenientes
Presentación Internet:ventajas e inconvenientesPresentación Internet:ventajas e inconvenientes
Presentación Internet:ventajas e inconvenientesNatalie
 
Porta.compressed
Porta.compressedPorta.compressed
Porta.compressedtatibooth
 
IAndaya CV - HR Ops and Payroll Manager_01292015
IAndaya CV - HR Ops and Payroll Manager_01292015IAndaya CV - HR Ops and Payroll Manager_01292015
IAndaya CV - HR Ops and Payroll Manager_01292015Israelita Andaya
 
Internet, Práctica 1
Internet, Práctica 1Internet, Práctica 1
Internet, Práctica 1Natalie
 
C.03-14 Banco Mundial reconoce a SC con una mención honorífica
C.03-14 Banco Mundial reconoce a SC con una mención honorífica C.03-14 Banco Mundial reconoce a SC con una mención honorífica
C.03-14 Banco Mundial reconoce a SC con una mención honorífica Superintendencia de Competencia
 
Skillsaudit 150906124841-lva1-app6892
Skillsaudit 150906124841-lva1-app6892Skillsaudit 150906124841-lva1-app6892
Skillsaudit 150906124841-lva1-app6892MulkacE147
 
Práctico n2 ppii2015
Práctico n2 ppii2015Práctico n2 ppii2015
Práctico n2 ppii2015Izaul Pierart
 
Innovate Fast or Die Slowly - The same choice for Media & Marketers
Innovate Fast or Die Slowly - The same choice for Media & MarketersInnovate Fast or Die Slowly - The same choice for Media & Marketers
Innovate Fast or Die Slowly - The same choice for Media & MarketersJonathan Bean
 
Cibercultura maestría bolivia slideshare
Cibercultura maestría bolivia slideshareCibercultura maestría bolivia slideshare
Cibercultura maestría bolivia slideshareMauricio Vásquez Arias
 
Pubcon 2016: Cross-Channel Paid PPC & Paid Social
Pubcon 2016: Cross-Channel Paid PPC & Paid SocialPubcon 2016: Cross-Channel Paid PPC & Paid Social
Pubcon 2016: Cross-Channel Paid PPC & Paid SocialMarketing Mojo
 

Viewers also liked (17)

GVK- Resume
GVK- ResumeGVK- Resume
GVK- Resume
 
Presentación Internet:ventajas e inconvenientes
Presentación Internet:ventajas e inconvenientesPresentación Internet:ventajas e inconvenientes
Presentación Internet:ventajas e inconvenientes
 
Porta.compressed
Porta.compressedPorta.compressed
Porta.compressed
 
Oblikovanje ponudbe manjših nastanitev v Ljubljani
Oblikovanje ponudbe manjših nastanitev v LjubljaniOblikovanje ponudbe manjših nastanitev v Ljubljani
Oblikovanje ponudbe manjših nastanitev v Ljubljani
 
IAndaya CV - HR Ops and Payroll Manager_01292015
IAndaya CV - HR Ops and Payroll Manager_01292015IAndaya CV - HR Ops and Payroll Manager_01292015
IAndaya CV - HR Ops and Payroll Manager_01292015
 
Internet, Práctica 1
Internet, Práctica 1Internet, Práctica 1
Internet, Práctica 1
 
MyC.V-6-2016ITI
MyC.V-6-2016ITIMyC.V-6-2016ITI
MyC.V-6-2016ITI
 
C.03-14 Banco Mundial reconoce a SC con una mención honorífica
C.03-14 Banco Mundial reconoce a SC con una mención honorífica C.03-14 Banco Mundial reconoce a SC con una mención honorífica
C.03-14 Banco Mundial reconoce a SC con una mención honorífica
 
FERNANDO MABBAYAD_CV FORM
FERNANDO MABBAYAD_CV FORMFERNANDO MABBAYAD_CV FORM
FERNANDO MABBAYAD_CV FORM
 
Skillsaudit 150906124841-lva1-app6892
Skillsaudit 150906124841-lva1-app6892Skillsaudit 150906124841-lva1-app6892
Skillsaudit 150906124841-lva1-app6892
 
Práctico n2 ppii2015
Práctico n2 ppii2015Práctico n2 ppii2015
Práctico n2 ppii2015
 
Jerry Peterson resume
Jerry Peterson resumeJerry Peterson resume
Jerry Peterson resume
 
Innovate Fast or Die Slowly - The same choice for Media & Marketers
Innovate Fast or Die Slowly - The same choice for Media & MarketersInnovate Fast or Die Slowly - The same choice for Media & Marketers
Innovate Fast or Die Slowly - The same choice for Media & Marketers
 
9/11 donde estabas tu hace 10 años?
9/11 donde estabas tu hace 10 años?9/11 donde estabas tu hace 10 años?
9/11 donde estabas tu hace 10 años?
 
Cibercultura maestría bolivia slideshare
Cibercultura maestría bolivia slideshareCibercultura maestría bolivia slideshare
Cibercultura maestría bolivia slideshare
 
Pubcon 2016: Cross-Channel Paid PPC & Paid Social
Pubcon 2016: Cross-Channel Paid PPC & Paid SocialPubcon 2016: Cross-Channel Paid PPC & Paid Social
Pubcon 2016: Cross-Channel Paid PPC & Paid Social
 
Creatividad Visual en diseño y otras areas
Creatividad Visual en diseño y otras areasCreatividad Visual en diseño y otras areas
Creatividad Visual en diseño y otras areas
 

Similar to Alberta's Environmental Farm Plan_A review by Tyler Kueber for Green Hectares

BC3 Policy Briefings: [2015-02] Modelling ecosystem services trade-offs in ag...
BC3 Policy Briefings: [2015-02] Modelling ecosystem services trade-offs in ag...BC3 Policy Briefings: [2015-02] Modelling ecosystem services trade-offs in ag...
BC3 Policy Briefings: [2015-02] Modelling ecosystem services trade-offs in ag...BC3 - Basque Center for Climate Change
 
Measures of the effects of agricultural practices on ecosystem services
Measures of the effects of agricultural practices on ecosystem servicesMeasures of the effects of agricultural practices on ecosystem services
Measures of the effects of agricultural practices on ecosystem servicesMichael Newbold
 
Presentation by Beccy Wilebore natcap research OECD INSPIRE Workshop Bio Risk...
Presentation by Beccy Wilebore natcap research OECD INSPIRE Workshop Bio Risk...Presentation by Beccy Wilebore natcap research OECD INSPIRE Workshop Bio Risk...
Presentation by Beccy Wilebore natcap research OECD INSPIRE Workshop Bio Risk...OECD Environment
 
To Review the Impact and Copping Strategies of Climate Change in Developing C...
To Review the Impact and Copping Strategies of Climate Change in Developing C...To Review the Impact and Copping Strategies of Climate Change in Developing C...
To Review the Impact and Copping Strategies of Climate Change in Developing C...AI Publications
 
T12 majdi gouja nena exec summary
T12 majdi gouja nena exec summaryT12 majdi gouja nena exec summary
T12 majdi gouja nena exec summaryNENAwaterscarcity
 
Climate and Water Quality Policy Design for Agriculture with Environmental Co...
Climate and Water Quality Policy Design for Agriculture with Environmental Co...Climate and Water Quality Policy Design for Agriculture with Environmental Co...
Climate and Water Quality Policy Design for Agriculture with Environmental Co...CrimsonpublishersMCDA
 
Agriculture System And Climate Change A Systematic Literature Review
Agriculture System And Climate Change  A Systematic Literature ReviewAgriculture System And Climate Change  A Systematic Literature Review
Agriculture System And Climate Change A Systematic Literature ReviewAndrew Parish
 
CAN PAYMENTS FOR ECOSYSTEM SERVICES REDUCE SOIL EROSION? THE CASE OF EASTERN ...
CAN PAYMENTS FOR ECOSYSTEM SERVICES REDUCE SOIL EROSION? THE CASE OF EASTERN ...CAN PAYMENTS FOR ECOSYSTEM SERVICES REDUCE SOIL EROSION? THE CASE OF EASTERN ...
CAN PAYMENTS FOR ECOSYSTEM SERVICES REDUCE SOIL EROSION? THE CASE OF EASTERN ...IAEME Publication
 
Economic Comparison of Effects of Clean Energy Legislation on Agriculture Sector
Economic Comparison of Effects of Clean Energy Legislation on Agriculture SectorEconomic Comparison of Effects of Clean Energy Legislation on Agriculture Sector
Economic Comparison of Effects of Clean Energy Legislation on Agriculture SectorAmerican Farmland Trust
 
The Environment And Corporate Environmental Impact On The...
The Environment And Corporate Environmental Impact On The...The Environment And Corporate Environmental Impact On The...
The Environment And Corporate Environmental Impact On The...Erin Rivera
 
climate_change_dialogue[1]
climate_change_dialogue[1]climate_change_dialogue[1]
climate_change_dialogue[1]Paul Cristofani
 
Climate change and water security concern in agriculture
Climate change and water security concern in agricultureClimate change and water security concern in agriculture
Climate change and water security concern in agricultureAnoop Shrestha
 
Smallholder farmers’ perception of the impacts of climate change and variabil...
Smallholder farmers’ perception of the impacts of climate change and variabil...Smallholder farmers’ perception of the impacts of climate change and variabil...
Smallholder farmers’ perception of the impacts of climate change and variabil...Alexander Decker
 
The Impacts of EnvironmentalRegulations on Competitiveness.docx
The Impacts of EnvironmentalRegulations on Competitiveness.docxThe Impacts of EnvironmentalRegulations on Competitiveness.docx
The Impacts of EnvironmentalRegulations on Competitiveness.docxarnoldmeredith47041
 
The Impacts of EnvironmentalRegulations on Competitiveness.docx
The Impacts of EnvironmentalRegulations on Competitiveness.docxThe Impacts of EnvironmentalRegulations on Competitiveness.docx
The Impacts of EnvironmentalRegulations on Competitiveness.docxrtodd33
 
General Introduction to the SYR: focus on the Social Science Aspect
General Introduction to the SYR: focus on the Social Science AspectGeneral Introduction to the SYR: focus on the Social Science Aspect
General Introduction to the SYR: focus on the Social Science Aspectipcc-media
 
Valuing Environmental Costs in Pakista
Valuing Environmental Costs in PakistaValuing Environmental Costs in Pakista
Valuing Environmental Costs in Pakistazubeditufail
 
Agriculture and climate change A Lecture By Mr Allah Dad Khan Former DG Agri...
Agriculture and climate change  A Lecture By Mr Allah Dad Khan Former DG Agri...Agriculture and climate change  A Lecture By Mr Allah Dad Khan Former DG Agri...
Agriculture and climate change A Lecture By Mr Allah Dad Khan Former DG Agri...Mr.Allah Dad Khan
 

Similar to Alberta's Environmental Farm Plan_A review by Tyler Kueber for Green Hectares (20)

BC3 Policy Briefings: [2015-02] Modelling ecosystem services trade-offs in ag...
BC3 Policy Briefings: [2015-02] Modelling ecosystem services trade-offs in ag...BC3 Policy Briefings: [2015-02] Modelling ecosystem services trade-offs in ag...
BC3 Policy Briefings: [2015-02] Modelling ecosystem services trade-offs in ag...
 
Measures of the effects of agricultural practices on ecosystem services
Measures of the effects of agricultural practices on ecosystem servicesMeasures of the effects of agricultural practices on ecosystem services
Measures of the effects of agricultural practices on ecosystem services
 
Presentation by Beccy Wilebore natcap research OECD INSPIRE Workshop Bio Risk...
Presentation by Beccy Wilebore natcap research OECD INSPIRE Workshop Bio Risk...Presentation by Beccy Wilebore natcap research OECD INSPIRE Workshop Bio Risk...
Presentation by Beccy Wilebore natcap research OECD INSPIRE Workshop Bio Risk...
 
MODELS.doc
MODELS.docMODELS.doc
MODELS.doc
 
To Review the Impact and Copping Strategies of Climate Change in Developing C...
To Review the Impact and Copping Strategies of Climate Change in Developing C...To Review the Impact and Copping Strategies of Climate Change in Developing C...
To Review the Impact and Copping Strategies of Climate Change in Developing C...
 
T12 majdi gouja nena exec summary
T12 majdi gouja nena exec summaryT12 majdi gouja nena exec summary
T12 majdi gouja nena exec summary
 
Climate and Water Quality Policy Design for Agriculture with Environmental Co...
Climate and Water Quality Policy Design for Agriculture with Environmental Co...Climate and Water Quality Policy Design for Agriculture with Environmental Co...
Climate and Water Quality Policy Design for Agriculture with Environmental Co...
 
Agriculture System And Climate Change A Systematic Literature Review
Agriculture System And Climate Change  A Systematic Literature ReviewAgriculture System And Climate Change  A Systematic Literature Review
Agriculture System And Climate Change A Systematic Literature Review
 
CAN PAYMENTS FOR ECOSYSTEM SERVICES REDUCE SOIL EROSION? THE CASE OF EASTERN ...
CAN PAYMENTS FOR ECOSYSTEM SERVICES REDUCE SOIL EROSION? THE CASE OF EASTERN ...CAN PAYMENTS FOR ECOSYSTEM SERVICES REDUCE SOIL EROSION? THE CASE OF EASTERN ...
CAN PAYMENTS FOR ECOSYSTEM SERVICES REDUCE SOIL EROSION? THE CASE OF EASTERN ...
 
Economic Comparison of Effects of Clean Energy Legislation on Agriculture Sector
Economic Comparison of Effects of Clean Energy Legislation on Agriculture SectorEconomic Comparison of Effects of Clean Energy Legislation on Agriculture Sector
Economic Comparison of Effects of Clean Energy Legislation on Agriculture Sector
 
The Environment And Corporate Environmental Impact On The...
The Environment And Corporate Environmental Impact On The...The Environment And Corporate Environmental Impact On The...
The Environment And Corporate Environmental Impact On The...
 
Sustainable Paper
Sustainable PaperSustainable Paper
Sustainable Paper
 
climate_change_dialogue[1]
climate_change_dialogue[1]climate_change_dialogue[1]
climate_change_dialogue[1]
 
Climate change and water security concern in agriculture
Climate change and water security concern in agricultureClimate change and water security concern in agriculture
Climate change and water security concern in agriculture
 
Smallholder farmers’ perception of the impacts of climate change and variabil...
Smallholder farmers’ perception of the impacts of climate change and variabil...Smallholder farmers’ perception of the impacts of climate change and variabil...
Smallholder farmers’ perception of the impacts of climate change and variabil...
 
The Impacts of EnvironmentalRegulations on Competitiveness.docx
The Impacts of EnvironmentalRegulations on Competitiveness.docxThe Impacts of EnvironmentalRegulations on Competitiveness.docx
The Impacts of EnvironmentalRegulations on Competitiveness.docx
 
The Impacts of EnvironmentalRegulations on Competitiveness.docx
The Impacts of EnvironmentalRegulations on Competitiveness.docxThe Impacts of EnvironmentalRegulations on Competitiveness.docx
The Impacts of EnvironmentalRegulations on Competitiveness.docx
 
General Introduction to the SYR: focus on the Social Science Aspect
General Introduction to the SYR: focus on the Social Science AspectGeneral Introduction to the SYR: focus on the Social Science Aspect
General Introduction to the SYR: focus on the Social Science Aspect
 
Valuing Environmental Costs in Pakista
Valuing Environmental Costs in PakistaValuing Environmental Costs in Pakista
Valuing Environmental Costs in Pakista
 
Agriculture and climate change A Lecture By Mr Allah Dad Khan Former DG Agri...
Agriculture and climate change  A Lecture By Mr Allah Dad Khan Former DG Agri...Agriculture and climate change  A Lecture By Mr Allah Dad Khan Former DG Agri...
Agriculture and climate change A Lecture By Mr Allah Dad Khan Former DG Agri...
 

Alberta's Environmental Farm Plan_A review by Tyler Kueber for Green Hectares

  • 2. Introduction: The global agriculture industry faces many conflicting ideologies as a result of two competing demands imposed on agricultural producers and policy makers; the production of food for a growing population and the reduction of the environmental impacts associated with that production (Robertson and Swinton 2005). Creating an effective policy to reduce agriculture pollution within Alberta presents many challenges due the diverse geological, political, and producer landscape resulting from contrasting productivism and environmentalism ideals. Pollution generated by agricultural activities presents many challenges because it generally involves a large number of diffuse pollution sources. The abatement practices associated with each form of pollution are generally unobservable making it difficult to regulate agricultural pollution in an efficient, cost-effective manner (Weersink et al 1998). Specific pollution sources examined in this brief are mainly crop inputs such as fertilizer and pesticide use. The agriculture input issues explored are not a comprehensive list of all environmental hazards created by agricultural activities, rather a focal point due to their effect on tangible issues such as soil and water quality. Specifically in Alberta and western Canada, the spatial distribution of heterogeneous agriculture producers across a large geographic area presents many additional challenges not only in the implementation of comprehensive, effective policy, but in the areas of monitoring and enforcement of policy initiatives. Soil and water quality, climate change, and the loss of wildlife habitat are likely to grow with further globalization and increasing resource scarcity, thus defining the need for effective environmental policy (Miranowski and Carlson 1993). Successful policy must be targeted at effective pollution reduction containing both economic and environmental dimensions to remediate some of the social cost caused by agricultural pollution. Environmental Policy Options: Weersink et al (1998) outlined many economic instruments policy makers could utilize to achieve environmental objectives in agriculture. This study examined the ability of alternative economic instruments to achieve environmental objectives. The study presents three main categories of instruments: (i) charges on subsidies; (ii) tradeable permits; and decentralized policies. Whether these instruments can be utilized in a cost-effective manner depends largely on the ability of the regulator to monitor and enforce the choices made by producers (Weersink et al, 1998). Determining an effective environmental policy instrument targeted at reducing Alberta’s agriculture pollution ultimately depends on which conditions exist among the agriculture industry provincially. Charges and Subsidies generally refer to an economic instrument (such as taxation) on emissions, ambient concentrations, or subsidies provided based on design-based application. In order for these individual instruments to be enforceable and effective, several socio- economic conditions must exist (summarized in table 1).
  • 3. Table 1. Conditions for economic instruments to be effective. Adapted from “Economic Instruments and Environmental Policy in Agriculture,” by Weersink, J. Livernois, J.E Shogren and J.S. Shortle, Canadian Public Policy,Vol. XXIV, p. 314. Copyright 1998 by JSTOR. Using a charge such as an emission tax or ambient fee, presents many problems when applied to the agriculture industry because the conditions for the instrument to be effective are not met. Some of these conditions include the inability to measure individual producer emissions at a reasonable cost. Since agriculture pollutants are generally from diffuse source occurring over a longer time period, an accurate relationship between estimated emissions and observable inputs is poorly defined (Braden and Segerson 1993). It would be difficult to effectively monitor resource quality over a large area such as Alberta due to the heterogeneous environment conditions (precipitation, soil type etc) and its influence on agronomic production. Therefore in order for a charge-based instrument to be accurate and effective, the input tax should in principle vary with location and application method (Zilberman, Khanna and Lipper 1997). Due to the diffuse source nature of environmental pollution resulting from agriculture, if a charge is implemented, it must be addressed by preventing the generation of the residuals at their source. Most other environmental policies associated with point-source problems such as those that exist in the energy industry attempt to control the delivery of the pollutant between its source and final delivery. This interception strategy cannot be applied to the agriculture industry (Weersink et al 1998). Although an input tax may
  • 4. reduce input use, another disadvantage of a pure tax is that it does not encourage any other abatement actions. These actions may be more cost-efficient options such as crop choice and tillage methods; therefore, the most cost-effective attainment of pollution is not always achieved through the use of a tax (Weersink et al 1998). Further to this, the inelasticity of farm input demand implies charges such as a tax rate must be substantially high to induce the desired reduction in input use. Therefore, it is unlikely such policy is politically feasible (Helfand & House 1995). The origin of non-point, diffuse source pollution is difficult to trace, therefore all policy options that require a monitoring or enforcing component are limited in feasibility and effectiveness. Instruments such as tradable permits in context of the agriculture industry could be based on inputs such as fertilizer. However, since pollution derived from fertilizer use is largely residual and heterogeneous in response to differing geological areas, agronomic requirements, size of farming operations and the effect on their respective environment, the relation between inputs and environmental problems lacks clear definition. Since individual firms specific contribution to an issue such as surface water quality is difficult to accurately quantify, issuing binding, effective permits would be difficult. Though capitalist efficiencies do exist in terms of a firms decision about design and location of pollution control equipment (opposed to regulator decision), choosing a tax rate on emissions or inputs requires full information on how polluters will respond to the charges. This information is not likely known by the polluters themselves in the short run, and suggests tax rate structures will have to be continually revised with changes in economic conditions (Weersink et al, 1998). Further to this, the definition of a polluter would have to be well-defined by a permit so that a sufficient market existed to make the permit actually tradable. As previously discussed, the heterogeneous composition of agriculture producers, various crop inputs, and geologic conditions prevent a standardized definition of a polluter. Decentralized policies such as liability rules, non-compliance fees, performance bonds and property rights definitions present many challenges as an economic instrument. Decentralized policies allow individuals to resolve environmental problems through the legal system or negotiations. Liability laws make polluters responsible for any damages they cause, while compliance fees target individuals polluting above an ambient standard target. Due to the nature of agriculture industry such as frequent pollution events, unclear cause and effect relationships involving many parties, and relatively unobservable actions of the polluter, the links between damage and causation are poorly defined. This makes a decentralized policy such as a non-compliance fee’s, liability laws and performance bonds also difficult to assess. Comparatively, in Alberta farmland is generally a privately owned resource where little market for ecosystem goods and services exists to the producer. Therefore property rights definition can influence whether the producer has access to market non-agriculture goods and services such as the hunting of wildlife. If property rights were defined to include wildlife on a producers land, a market may exist for an ecosystem good such as hunting which could offset
  • 5. the producers decline in agronomic-productivity for actions such as habitat preservation (Weersink et al 1998). Moreover, Weeersink et al (1998) suggests rather than relying on the best solution though economic instruments, the most effective way of dealing with diffuse source pollution in agriculture may be technological developments and business lead initiatives. Technological developments are generally correlated to business lead initiatives to provide producers with funding needed to adapt technology. The prominent ideal here is that technological advancements focus on a more accurate and efficient utilization of inputs such as fertilizers and pesticides. Through more efficient use, quantity of inputs may be reduced and their effect on the environment minimized. Policy makers generally use a subsidy mechanism to encourage producers to adopt the most modern precision agriculture technology because adaptations are generally costly to implement. Like a tax, subsidies can occur based on inputs or outputs relative to production. Several disadvantages of a subsidy mechanism include cost-ineffectiveness, universal availability and inefficient allocation of subsidy funding (Weersink et al 1998). Alberta’s Environmental Agriculture Policy: Alberta’s Environmental Farm Plan is a policy that uses subsidy-based instruments to initiate environmental awareness and land stewardship through the adoption of beneficial management practices applicable to agriculture. Awareness objectives are achieved through the producer documentation of environmental liabilities. Alberta’s Environmental Farm Plan (EFP) provides producers with access to subsidies upon proof of strategic environmental plans, contained in a document submitted by the producer. These subsidies provide incentive and assist producers in adopting strategies to mitigate the effects of agriculture production. Such mitigation strategies may include the adoption of precision-based technologies made available by a subsidy. By definition, Alberta’s EFP is a cross compliance policy. This refers to a program that ties eligibility for agricultural support to meeting a specific environmental criterion. Farmer, Rancher and Producer Incentive: The Environmental Farm Plan (EFP) is a voluntary, whole farm, self-assessment tool that helps producers identify their environmental risks and develop plans to mitigate identified risks. A diverse range of producers are attracted to the Environmental Farm Plan (EFP) program because it helps them identify and address environmental risks in their respective operation, while increasing their understanding of legal requirements related to environmental issues. Protecting water, air and soil quality is key to the sustainable production of crops and livestock thus it is a vested interest to producers. An EFP will identify what a producer is already mitigating effectively and pinpoint where improvement in
  • 6. environmental hazard mitigation can occur. Many producers value this information because they are focused on leaving a farm legacy for future generations thus focusing on water, air, and soil quality is a primary objective. By addressing some of these risks in an EFP, producers may additionally increase operational efficiency by reassessing fertilizer use or monitoring of fuel storage tanks for example. Upon completion of an EFP, many farmers and ranchers are available to receive funding to aid in the adoption of precision agriculture technologies if it correlates to one of the beneficial management practices stated in their EFP. Producers are attracted to precision agriculture technology because this technology can increase the efficiency of machinery and input use. Precision agriculture can provide producers with an opportunity to simultaneously reduce environmental impacts while improving productivity and profits on the farm (Bongiovanni and Lowenberg- DeBoer 2004). Projects available for funding through Growing Forward II under the EFP are quite comprehensive and include but are not limited to projects such as agriculture watershed enhancement, biosecurity, on-farm energy management, confined feeding operation stewardship etc. Further to this, the EFP promotes producers to pair environmental stewardship with agricultural production which can be used in the marketing of agri-products. Consumers in modern day Canadian society are increasingly concerned about the safety and quality of the food produced within the nation. Sustainable sourcing is becoming a requirement of many major food purchasers, from manufacturers to restaurants. Thus, completing an EFP appeals to producers because it demonstrates to the public, government, and investors that farmers and ranchers are managing their environmental risks. This program is largely voluntary, thus agriculture producers perceive this program as attainable and viable. Producers adapting environmental hazard mitigation strategies can do so at their convenience and are able to prioritize tasks based on their specific operation. This flexibility and attainability is a crucial factor determining the success and adaptation of this provincial initiative. Since its inception in 2003 the Alberta Environmental Farm Plan has had 8000 completed plans which represents 24% of Alberta farms and just under two million acres of agriculture land (Alberta Environmental Farm Plan, 2016). Analysis of the Environmental Farm Plan: One of the main incentives for producers to enrol in the Environmental Farm Plan is their access to funding which aids in the adaptation of new technologies possible of increasing farm operational efficiency. Determining the effectiveness of precision based technologies can indicate the effectiveness of Alberta’s EFP at achieving environmental objectives. Schieffer & Dillon (2015) studied several precision agriculture technologies (auto- steer tractor, variable rate nitrogen application, and a sprayer with automatic section control) and their affect on the economic, agronomic, and environmental performance of the farms in their study. Additionally, they correlated the adoption
  • 7. of precision agriculture technologies and their interactions with different types of agro-environmental policies (emission limits and taxes) and the change in relative effectiveness of those policies. Understanding these impacts provides insight for the effectiveness of Alberta’s Environmental Farm Plan in terms of its incentives (subsidies) for producers to adapt the same precision agricultural technologies. Schieffer & Dillon (2015) suggest: “policy failure can occur when such policy is designed for traditional production methods and fails to allow for the changes in abatement costs associated with adoption of precision agriculture methods. Although incentive-based policies are often desirable for pursuing economic efficiency and cost-effectiveness when pollution sources have heterogeneous abatement costs, policies designed without information about the technology mix used by farms may be limited in their effectiveness in reaching environmental goals. Quantity-based policies (e.g., quotas) may be more robust to technological change or uncertainty in terms of achieving targeted environmental improvements.” Bongiovanni & Lowenburg (2004) also support this idea and suggest precision agriculture can lead to higher marginal abatement costs in the form of forgone profits, decreasing producers’ responsiveness to those policies. Similarly, this analysis suggests that Alberta’s EFP in terms of promoting the adoption of precision methods, may be ineffective at mitigating environmental hazards with this incentive based mechanism alone. Assuming Alberta’s abatement costs are largely heterogeneous due to the geological variation, spatial distribution, and production variations across the province, this may be ineffective at actually achieving overall environmental improvements. Subsidies to support the adaptation of precision based technologies may be more effective at achieving environmental improvements in combination with input quantity-based limits or taxes on pollution. Problems with a subsidy-based instrument can be seen if we assume adoption of technology leads to an increase in use efficiencies of crop inputs perceived by all producers. This adoption of this technology would actually make any reduction target less binding. This adoption is less binding because the farmer actually needs less reduction in nitrogen for example, in order to meet pre-existing reduction targets. Essentially the reduction of inputs gained by technological advances is offset by the producers continued input use at a less binding level. In this case, the marginal abatement cost of pollution is actually higher with the technological adaptation, so the producer has less incentive to reduce his input use further. Therefore, without an adaptable limit or tax that can be binding, the producer has no incentive to further reduce pollution caused by inputs. Scheiffer & Dillon (2015) explored the use of a tax and a limit as a policy instrument in combination with technology subsidy policy. With the adoption of multiple technologies, the tax policies were less effective than were the limit policies in reducing environmental impacts. This was exhibited by the larger decrease in net return for tax policies and the greater decrease in nitrogen use for limit policies in
  • 8. comparison to the adaptation of base technology individually (Scheiffer & Dillon, 2015, pg. 57). In order to make Alberta’s EFP more effective at achieving pollution reduction targets, a quantity-based limit would be the most beneficial instrument. To be most effective, this limit would have to correspond with the specific adopted technology and the responding effect on marginal abatement cost (Scheiffer & Dillon 2015). However, since this program is largely voluntary compliance, a quantity based limit would have to be a provincial mandate spanning all industry in order to ensure compliance of those participating in the EFP were not at a disadvantage. Extensive monitoring and enforcement efforts would be needed to ensure limit compliance across the province. The political and economic feasibility of these extensive measures poses as a barrier to using a quantity-based limit to increase policy effectiveness. In Alberta, upon adaptation of precision-based technologies, producers have the opportunities to participate in the Agricultural Carbon Offsets Market. This carbon-offset market is a government incentive intended to further reduce the abatement cost of agricultural related pollution in terms of carbon emissions. Similar to the EFP, this component is voluntary, however farmers and ranchers do get paid for their efforts to reduce emissions. Although this has moderate financial rewards, it provides a new opportunity for income, one that has the potential to become a more developed market in the future. Though this incentive is not exclusive to the EFP, used in combination with the EFP may increase producer incentive to reduce pollution based on mitigation strategies. Moreover, as a market for carbon-offsets is developed, this instrument may gain ground in terms of providing more incentives to producers resulting in greater adoption of carbon reduction strategies. Schieffer & Dillon (2015) also suggests that the adoption of multiple technologies such as auto- steer tractor, variable rate nitrogen application, and automatic section control is more effective at achieving environmental improvements than adopting one technology alone. This suggests that the subsidies available through programs such as Growing Forward II-upon the completion of an EFP, may be more effective if they are linked to multiple adaptations. However, the cost of adopting multiple technologies ultimately places the burden on economic feasibility for the producer and the viability of their enterprise when it comes to implementing these changes. One could suggest a solution is to make more funding available through the subsidy framework such as Growing Forward II, but this ultimately leads to the issue of funding for the subsidies; who is paying for these subsidies, and if the investment is still efficient at reducing environmental hazards at this new cost. This point is supported by the Weersink et al (1998) study, which suggests a major downfall of subsidy policy is the fact that is it incompatible with debt reduction- a major goal of most governments. Moreover, the subsidy incentives linked to Alberta’s Environmental Farm Plan are subject to the same criticisms discussed by Weersink et al (1998); greatest pollution contributors may not apply
  • 9. to a cost-sharing program if the incentive is insufficient; funding may be inefficiently allocated in terms of its availability to non-polluting firms; and inefficient allocation of funding to firms that would have adopted the abatement regardless. An additional problem with Alberta’s Environmental Farm Plan is the lack of enrolment by large producers. From the EFP statistic presented in the introduction, the average size of farm completing a plan is 250 acres. This largely suggests that the majority of large farms, or corporate farms have not completed an EFP. Lack of enrollment in terms of large commodity producers is possibly because these large producers do not reap the same rewards as other smaller producers. This could be because large-scale producers do not rely as heavily on subsidy funding available through programs such as Growing Forward II. One could argue that is policy is ineffective for larger, less financially constrained producers because the marginal cost of pollution abatement may higher to these producers than to smaller producers. An additional explanation could suggest that the benefits in reducing pollution residuals are difficult to assess, therefore large farms less reliant on funding do not have any additional incentives to promote compliance (Weersink et al 1998). Overall enrollment, specifically large farm enrollment, questions the effectiveness of the EFP to reduce diffuse point source pollution, as some of the largest contributors may not be adapting best management practices or mitigating environmental hazards. However, if these practices provide economic incentive on their own, the producers may adapt them without enrolling in the EFP. In either regard, lack of data around program enrollment and technology utilization make it difficult to assess the differing abatement costs perceived by the heterogeneous groups of producers. This knowledge gap limits the accuracy of instruments that could be employed to make the incentive greater. Overall, the effectiveness of this subsidy incentive depends on whether it is fact a pollution-contributing farmer that is enrolled in the program, and the magnitude of the individual’s pollution reduction as a result of program compliance. In the future, issues such as sustainable sourcing for agri-products are expected to be increasingly in demand in the marketplace. Another incentive type mechanism employed by the EFP is the establishment of sustainable sourcing criteria. The Alberta Environmental Farm Plan in particular has partnered with Alberta Barley on a project to determine whether sustainable sourcing standards within the EFP meet global standards. Determination of these standards could foster marketplace premiums for Canadian products produced under these conditions. Based on this incentive, the EFP holds great future value to producers, as it is a tool that can aid in achieving environmental objectives correlated with attaining sustainable sourcing status. Due to the relatively undefined existing standards in terms of global standards, the future effectiveness of this incentive is largely unknown at this time. Additional to agriculture input use and sustainable sourcing guidelines, the EFP recently added a new Species at Risk (SAR) component. This component is largely based around promoting habitat conservation for species at risk by arming
  • 10. producers with an online tool to identify opportunities to conserve those species at risk on their agricultural land. This implementation has incentive as it can potentially links to other issues such as sustainable sourcing status. Through the adaptation of the SAR component, sustainable sourcing status may be unattainable to the producer if species at risk are present on agricultural land. Producers are motivated by the market place advantage of labels such as sustainable sourcing, therefore habitat conservation may be a priority depending on the net gain perceived by the producer as a result of this implementation. Though the awareness of conservation ideals for species at risk is enhanced with this component, the net gain to the producer will not be enough based on market place premiums alone. Furthermore this added component targets the potential for producer compensation in response to habitat conservation on agricultural lands. In other provinces, habitat conservation is currently funded by Environment and Climate Change Canada’s Species at Risk Partnerships on Agricultural Lands program. Though in effect in other provinces, the effectiveness of this instrument in Alberta is questionable because other decentralized-type of policies already exist outside the EFP framework. Other national initiatives such as the Ducks Unlimited program represent pre-existing decentralized policies in terms of its impact to property right economics and habitat conservation. The Ducks Unlimited variation allows land owners to sell conservation easements against the title of the land in return for restricting land use to practices that would preserve habitat. Though Ducks Unlimited primarily corresponds to wetland conservation, other initiatives such as Buck for Wildlife are already in existence. In order for this component to be more effective than the decentralized policies already in existence, more extensive compensation under this component will be needed in order to increased enrollment if that is the policy goal. One exception to this could be species that are not already protected under the Species at Risk Act and/or species not targeted by other decentralized policies. In this case, in order to be an effective instrument, the SAR component included under the EFP would need to be more specialized and pertain to the loopholes that other decentralized policies do not already address. Overall, the same monitoring and enforcement issues that reduce the Species at Risk Act effectiveness will also limit the effectiveness of this EFP component. Additional to promoting the most efficient technology and habitat conservation through incentives, another the main initiative within the EFP is to educate and increase awareness of environmental issues to the farming and ranching communities. Though education and awareness cannot be equated with quantifiable pollution reduction, its impacts on the producer ideals may provide ecological benefits that exist, however in a less tangible way. Through the use of education and awareness concepts, the EFP focuses on sustainability for future generations. This focus on future generations can use the concept of moral suasion to changing producer ideals of “good farming”. This can lead to a shift from the formerly productivist “good farming” ideals to more sustainability oriented ideals (Burton and Paragahawewa, 2011). Although difficult to assess, the increase of sustainability-focused ideals promoted by the EFP can lead to greater program compliance through adaptation of environmentally friendly practices. In turn, this
  • 11. creates some additional value for Alberta’s environmental farm plan and its ability to increase land stewardship initiatives. Conclusion: Overall, Alberta’s Environmental Farm Plan is an effective policy instrument to mitigate the effects of agricultural pollution. Though many criticisms of this incentive based policy exist, undoubtedly, it promotes agricultural land stewardship while offering flexibility and attainability to foster producer appeal and political feasibility. The program’s flexibility extends to reach Alberta’s farming and ranching communities so that the Environmental Farm Plan may be adopted and utilized by a wide range of producers with differing interests and ideals. Additional economic instruments have been explored to increase the effectiveness of this policy such as an input quantity-based limit. Many issues characteristic of the agriculture industry act as a barrier that prevents these economic instruments from being employed effectively. For those enrolled, Alberta’s Environmental Farm plan helps producers attain greater social license. Farmers participating in the Environmental Farm Plan are proving their due diligence to society on environmental issues. In a society that increasingly demands more accountability from landowners, Alberta’s Environmental Farm Plan is a framework that aids agriculture producers in their pursuit of becoming efficient, effective and responsible stewards of the land.
  • 12. References Braden, J.B. and K. Segerson (1993)."Information Problems in the Design of Nonpoint-Source Pollution Policy," in Theory, Modeling and Experience in the Management of Nonpoint-Source Pollution, ed. C.S. Russell and J.F. Shogren (Boston: Kluwer Academic Publishers). Bongiovanni, R., & Lowenberg-DeBoer, J. (2004). “Precision agriculture and sustainability.” Precision Agriculture, 5(4), 359–387. Burton, R.F. and Paragahawewa, U.H. (2011). “Creating culturally sustainable agri-environmental schemes.” Journal of Rural Studies, 27 (2011), pp. 95–104. Helfand, G.E. and B.W. House (1995). "Regulating Nonpoint Source Pollution under Heterogeneous Conditions," American Journal of Agricultural Economics 77(4):1024-32. Miranowski, J.A. and G.A. Carlson (1993). "Agricultural Resource Economics: An Overview," in Agricultural and Environmental Resource Economics, ed. G.A. (New York: Oxford University Press). Robertson, G. P., & Swinton, S. (2005). Reconciling agricultural productivity and environmental integrity: a grand challenge for agriculture. Frontiers in Ecology and the Environment, 3(1), 38–46. Schieffer, J., & Dillon, C. (2015). “The economic and environmental impacts of precision agriculture and interactions with agro-environmental policy.” Precision Agriculture, 16(1), 46-61. doi:10.1007/s11119-014-9382-5. Weersink, A., Livernois, J., Shogren, J. F., & Shortle, J. S.. (1998). “Economic Instruments and Environmental Policy in Agriculture.” Canadian Public Policy / Analyse De Politiques, 24(3), 309–327. Zilberman, D., M. Khanna and L. Lipper (1997). "Economics of New Technologies for Sustainable Agriculture." Australian Journal of Agricultural and Resource Economics 41(1):63-80.