SlideShare a Scribd company logo
1 of 107
Forthcoming in Chris Coyne and Rachel Coyne – “Floors and
Ceilings - the economics of price controls”, London: IEA
Hobart Paperback.
The Simple Economics of Wage Floors
W S Siebert January 2015
Birmingham University
ABSTRACT
The paper surveys minimum wages setting and finds adverse
employment effects broadly in line with conventional economic
models. UK studies generally report small effects, but the UK is
poorly suited for measurement given confounding changes in
welfare benefits and no regional variation. Clarity is found in
better empirical settings such as Canada, with good minimum
wage variations and provincial differences, and in the OECD
country panels. Case studies are also reviewed including South
Africa (minimum wages as a white supremacy weapon),
Portugal (extended collective agreements being analogous to
minimum wages, and reducing employment), and Greece (the
minimum encouraging temporary work). Alternative ways of
helping the poor via encouragement of stable families, more
competitive school systems, and subsidies for low paid work are
advanced.
“My daughter’s ambition is to get a job in an office. She has
Down’s syndrome. She thinks that, if she works hard, someone,
somewhere will give her a job. At £6.50 per hour, it’s never
going to happen. But at £2 per hour? Maybe.” (Letter to Daily
Telegraph 17/1/0/14, from Candice Baxter)
“There is now no sizeable lobby in the UK campaigning for the
abolition of the minimum wage….In a poll of experts by the
Institute for Government the minimum wage was voted the most
successful UK government policy of the past 30 years, ahead of
the Northern Ireland peace process” (Manning 2013, 65)
Introduction
A wage floor such as the minimum wage makes payment of low
wages illegal. Such a floor clearly tends to reduce unskilled job
opportunities, yet it is only one example of floors under
working conditions placed by regulation. Other floors on terms
and conditions of employment relate to requirements for
protection against unfair dismissal, or against discrimination, or
for the provision of pensions via“autoenrolment”. Moreover, we
must remember that high welfare benefits also place a type of
floor under wages, since for many it is not worth working for a
wage lower than the welfare payments they can receive. The
adverse effects of these floors can compound each other,
particularly in a high tax environment, as we will show. High
floors can also be imposed by union power, especially via
extended collective agreements as in France.
The minimum wage from the beginning has been justified by the
Low Pay Commission (e.g. LPC 2000, para 3.18) as a means of
achieving “equity in the workplace”. But, in most private sector
businesses, equity is already achieved, in the sense that wages
approximate the revenue product of the marginal worker.
Private sector competition drives this result though the public
sector of course does not fit this model so easily. If low wages
are made illegal, then what happens is that the least productive
workers cannot be employed. This result is demonstrated most
clearly in the case of disabled workers, as shown in our opening
quotation above. As Candice Baxter points out in her letter, her
daughter could gain employment at £2 per hour, but certainly
not at £6.50. One’s heart goes out to her. The celebrations of
the politicians in the Institute for Government, shown in our
second quotation from Professor Manning, are premature.
Wage floors and other regulations of working conditions grow
together with centralised government, and are a part of the EU
dirigiste tradition. The 1989 EU Charter on Fundamental Social
Rights of Workers Rights marks a watershed (see Addison and
Siebert, 1994), and has subsequently become the Social Chapter
of the 1992 Treaty of Maastricht and 1997 Treaty of
Amsterdam. The Social Chapter sets floors to most aspects of
employment conditions, including “fair remuneration”, working
hours, freedom of association/unionisation, training, equal
treatment for men and women (and others), compulsory worker
consultative councils, and health and safety. In EU terms
(Commission 2006, p5), “the purpose of labour law is to offset
the inherent economic and social inequality within the
employment relationship”. In other words, decent wages and
conditions are due to the efforts of politicians. Thus, the role of
free markets and freedom of movement in defending the under-
privileged is misunderstood.
Setting minimum wages is easy, but deals with the symptoms of
low pay, not the causes. The political payoff from minimum
wage laws is immediate. The dispersion of wages is reduced,
and, since more women are low paid, so is the difference
between male and female average pay (another misleading
statistic). Yet nothing is done about the real problems in the
labour market and the education system (see Kristian Niemietz
2012). The low level of skills acquired by children from our
many single parent families is ignored, as is the worklessness
among these families (see below)[footnoteRef:1]. As for really
disadvantaged groups such as the disabled, the minimum wage
may do much harm. Opportunities may also be reduced for
students who are prevented from taking low paid internships
(and may have to volunteer instead), and for those whose main
work is in the home, but who would like to obtain some work to
supplement household income or gain the benefits of socialising
at work. The best that can be said of the minimum wage policy
is that it is irrelevant to real problems of inequality and
worklessness. More likely, it is part of a package combined with
other floors on working conditions, strong unions and high
taxes which make matters worse – as exemplified by Greece. [1:
26% of dependent children aged 0-18 live in single-parent
families in the UK, which is almost twice as high as in France
and Germany. The proportion of children being brought up in
jobless families is consequently also high, around 20% (see
OECD 2011a Tables 1.1 and LMF1.1A) which reduces these
children’s education and employment prospects.]
Our plan is next to consider research into the UK’s national
minimum wage, which is difficult given the lack of regional
variation and the confounding effects of high levels of welfare
payments. Then, we will take up results from Canada and the
US where provincial variation in the minimum gives a more
suitable design for minimum wage evaluation. We will also
discuss the interesting case of South Africa where minimum
wages were for a time used as a weapon in the struggle for
white supremacy. Here we will also discuss results from long
OECD country panels, which arguably give the best design for
minimum wage evaluation. Finally we will extend the
discussion to consider effects of minimum wages set by
collective agreement. Such minima are more detailed and
intrusive as shown by Martins’ (2014) study of the “30,000
minimum wages” set by collective agreements in Portugal.
UK Evidence on Employment Effects
The UK is the worst place conceivable to test for minimum
wage employment effects. Changes in the minimum have been
quite small, they are country-wide (so there is no clear
counterfactual), and they are carefully tailored to the
unemployment situation so as not to exacerabate unemployment
unduly. (The economists on the Low Pay Commission are
apolitical, and well aware of negative employment effects).
Compounding the problem is the changing welfare system which
also affects employment. We should remember that in 1999, at
the same time as the minimum wage was implemented, the
government introduced Working Family Tax Credits designed to
encourage work which would obviously tend to counteract
minimum wage effects in the opposite direction. However, the
UK research does need to be considered, if only to show that we
need to be careful before concluding (see for example Leonard
et al 2014) from small measured UK minimum wage effects that
conventional labour market models do not work.
The confounding effect of movements in welfare entitlements is
shown in Figure 1. Here simple demand (D) and supply (S)
curves are drawn for the unskilled labour market. If a minimum
wage is imposed, equilibrium moves from point E to point A.
However, if welfare benefits are brought in, or raised above the
minimum, then employment falls further, to point B. If welfare
benefits are pre-existing, then the impact of the minimum wage
on employment will be muted. The diagram is a simplification,
because apprentices and trainees will continue working for less
than welfare benefits, as we discuss later. Also, welfare benefits
– certainly in the UK – may vary with income from
employment, so that some people receive some benefits even if
they are earning a wage below the welfare floor. But the
tendency remains – there is an interaction between the welfare
system and the minimum wage.. Moreover, if welfare benefits
are reduced, or reformed via tax credits conditional on work,
employment will increase, confusing minimum wage effects.
Table 1 shows welfare trends, including the important housing
assistance component. Unfortunately this series on net
replacement rates is not available prior to 2001, however we can
analyse most of the period since the introduction of the
minimum wage. As can be seen, replacement rates have declined
in France and Germany (the Hartz reforms), increased for single
people in the US, and increased for families but not for single
people in the UK. In fact, the UK’s family replacement rates are
now amongst the most generous in the OECD (Niemietz 2012,
p46). However, some of the welfare is contingent on working at
least 16 hours, and so encourages some work. In fact, Gregg et
al (2012, p22) estimate that employment of single women rose
by 4% when tax credits were introduced: this worked against
minimum wage effects oon employment.
Figure 2 demonstrates two important points about the progress
of wages after the minimum was introduced. First, we see that a
substantial number of people were freely working for low wages
in 1998 prior to the implementation of the minimum. About 6%
of the workforce is in that lower tail which grades slowly down
to zero, reflecting the alternatives and productivity levels of the
individuals concerned. Here Mrs Baxter’s daughter would have
found her job.
Secondly, we see that even after the minimum was introduced,
many wish to be paid below it. Low pay is a continuing
phenomenon, with currently about 200,000 adults (21 and over,
i.e. 1% of the adult workforce) paid below the minimum (LPC
2014, p133). In fact, the real total is probably double this figure
(Kay 2007, p35) when we add the large number of under 21s.
Much of this non-compliance occurs with apprentices, who are
quite happy to receive low wages while training, as do students
in general. In fact, about 70% of 18-20 year old hairdressing
apprentices (LPC 2014, p134) currently refuse to accept the
minimum wage, for which of course the Low Pay Commission
and trade unions wrongly blame the employer. A further group
are the interns and volunteers, who do not enter wage
distributions like Figure 1 at all, but whom the Commission sees
as unfairly avoiding its system. The important point is that
many people see it worthwhile to work for low or no wages.
This is particularly true for students and others training in order
to raise their future wages.[footnoteRef:2] [2: See Gorry [2013,
p72) for a good paper on how the minimum wage obstructs
training: “Inexperienced workers are unable to pay for their
training through reductions in their wages. To gain experience,
they must maintain employment in a segment of the labor
market characterized by high job separation rates” – their
probability of unemployment consequently rises.]
A good study of adverse employment effects is provided by
Dickens et al (2012), who focus on part-time women where
coverage by the minimum is about 10%, twice as high as for
full-timers (LPC 2014, Fig 2.1). They establish a counterfactual
by comparing part-timers whose wages are raised by the
minimum to those paid just above that level, i.e. 10% above.
This comparison group will have similar skills and welfare
benefit options. They find that the introduction of the minimum
in 1999 caused the year-on-year probability of part-time women
retaining a job to fall from around 0.70 to 0.65. Another way of
putting this finding is that before the minimum wage, median
job duration was about 1.9 years for part-time women earning
around the minimum, falling to 1.7 years after the minimum,
that is, a fall of around 10%. They do not find effects caused by
the up-ratings as they have been too small to have much effect.
For example, the recent up-rating from £6.31 to £6.50 gives a
maximum uplift of 1.5% to about 5% of the workforce. As well
as being small relative to welfare benefit changes, minimum
wage increases have been lower in times of recession. Overall,
this means that it is difficult to detect effects of changes in the
minimum wage, but this result does not mean that higher
increases in the future will be harmless.
While minimum wage increases so far have been small, a
further piece of research by Rebecca Riley (2013) brings out the
negative effects of the altogether larger change that the
introduction of a minimum wage equal to the “living wage”
would have (see also Siebert 2014). Currently the “living wage”
is calculated to be £7.65 outside London, and £8.80 in London
(Living Wage “Commission”, 2014). Such a change would mean
wage increases for about 25% of the workforce rather than 5%,
and raise labour costs of young unskilled (non-university)
workers by as much as 14% in sectors such as hotels and
catering, and retailing. Riley shows not only that the demand
elasticity for labour is negative, but also that cross-price
elasticities are generally positive, precisely in accordance with
conventional economic theory. In other words, when the wage
of the young inexperienced and unskilled group goes up, their
employment falls, and the employment of substitutes such as
educated workers and older workers increases. Thus, 300,000
young unskilled workers will lose their jobs, but some skilled
and older workers will gain, so the overall loss of jobs is
reduced to 160,000. Increasing the minimum wage to the living
wage change would thus enable the older, better educated
workers to gain at the expense of unskilled youth, as happens in
France, but of course with serious long-term consequences for
those trapped outside the labour market.
The current dark situation for Britain’s unskilled youth is shown
in Tables 2 and 3, covering the period since the minimum wage
began. Table 2 shows that labourforce participation has declined
for all the disadvantaged groups except the disabled (whose
participation remains low). Admittedly it appears that our youth
participation rate is still better than that in France. But the UK
lags on another measure which is shown in Table 3, the percent
of 15-19s in the not in education, employment or training
(NEET) group. Here we see that the UK’s percentage has been
growing and at 9.5 % is the worst of the five major economies
shown, and worse than the OECD average. In summary, Tables
2 and 3 show that the inequality of life chances has been
growing, despite the Low Pay Commission’s mission to reduce
“inequity in the workplace”.
People who reject the orthodox explanation for the small UK
minimum wage effects need an alternative, They bring forward
ideas of single buyer power (i.e., “monopsony” – see Manning
2013), or of “efficiency wages” (Leonard et al 2014) to explain
the perceived market failure. Ironically, these two theories have
diametrically opposed views of what happens in free markets.
The monopsony theory implies that wages are too low: firms
operate with unfilled vacancies, because raising wages enough
to eliminate the backlog would require pay increases for all. But
the efficiency wage theory implies that wages are in a sense
“too high”: wages are above the market-clearing rate because
paying well is a cheap way to help supervisors generate extra
employee effort.
In fact neither theory fits well with the UK firm size structure
which is shown in Table 4. We see that the UK has 3.6 million
enterprises which only employ the owner, and obviously have
no monopsony power or difficulty with supervision. There are
also 1.2 million enterprises which employ workers, but the vast
majority of these, 97%, employ fewer than 50 workers, and
again can have no monopsony power or supervision issues. In
fact, it is only the 6 thousand firms that employ more than 250
to which these theories might apply. However, these firms tend
to pay higher wages in any case and so the minimum wage is
broadly irrelevant for them. It is much more likely that
unskilled and inexperienced workers lose from the minimum,
and indeed their unemployment rises more than proportionately
as the minimum rises, as shown in Gorry’s (2013) elegant model
Monopsony and efficiency wage theories would seem irrelevant
here.
International Evidence
It is fair to say that the UK evidence on the minimum wage does
not find large employment effects. It does find some disturbing
trends. However, the background to the UK’s minimum wage
ensures that any statistical analysis is likely to lead to
inconclusive results. For a more successful analysis, we need to
look at countries where there is high variation of the minimum
either for regions within a country, as in Canada or the USA, or
at the variation provided by cross-country panels. A country
with low welfare payments (e.g. the US) is also easier to
analyse. Let us consider first Canadian and US results, and then
examine South Africa which starkly underlines how minimum
wages can be misused by skilled workers to cut out unskilled
competition.[footnoteRef:3] [3: Another interesting country to
consider could be France with its exceptionally high minimum
(Gorry 2013). But France presents the same problems as the
UK, that is, lack of within-country variation, plus the
confounders of high welfare payments and high taxes. China is
also a possibility, with good variation provided by different
minimum wages in different cities. Fang and Lin (2013) provide
evidence of strong negative minimum wage effects using city
data which are better than the province data used by Wang and
Gunderson (2012) who find inconclusive effects at least for
Eastern China. However, China is too early to draw conclusions
from yet, since it is so large and heterogeneous with
complications of migrant labour and a large state-owned sector.
There is also research on minimum wages in LDCs in general,
bringing in non-compliance issues in the informal sector, which
we will touch on below.
]
Canada provides one of the best conditions for research into the
effects of minimum wages, since the ten Canadian provinces
have different minimum wage policies, sometimes with
considerable bite. Good time series data are also available. A
convincing body of Canadian literature has thus built up,
starting with Baker et al’s (1999) study of 9 provinces over
1975-1993. This study finds that a 10% increase in the
minimum reduces teenage employment by 2.5%, and that it
takes 6 years for the full effect to be revealed. Canadian data
are also used in the recent study for 1997-2008 by Campolieti et
al (2014, 587), who find a short-run elasticity of -0.16 for the
15-24 year group. Importantly, they note that their method
cannot capture long-run minimum wage effects (since they
follow individuals for only 6 months), and recommend doubling
this elasticity to derive the full picture. This would lead to a
long run elasticity of demand for labour of about -0.3, meaning
that a 10% increase in the minimum wage would reduce
employment by about 3% among the affected group. A similar
finding for teen employment is made by Sen et al (2011).
Interestingly, older workers’ employment appears to increase
with minimum wage increases (Fang and Gunderson 2009),
suggesting they are substituted for less productive youths, as we
have already seen for the UK. The minimum’s adverse effect
using good data thus becomes clearer.
A possible reason for the clarity of the Canadian effect is that
Canada’s minimum wage workers tend more to be in the
tradeable goods, exporting sectors. In this situation, a higher
minimum quickly undermines competitiveness and causes
employment reduction. The position is different if minimum
wage workers are concentrated in non-tradeable activities such
as retailing or construction (as in the UK). In this case, a rise in
the minimum wage simply “takes wages out of competition” and
this result can even be advantageous, especially for large firms
(see Cox and Oaxaca 1982, more recently Neumark and
Wascher 2008). Costs go up, but the increase is faced by
everyone, and prices can increase to offset this given the
absence of overseas competition. This factor might account for
the weaker disemployment results found in the US studies (e.g.
Addison et al 2012) of the restaurant sector noted below.
Magruder’s (2013) study of minimum wages in Indonesia
emphasises the importance of whether the sectors mainly
affected are in the tradeable or non-tradeable sectors.
Turning to research on the US, there is now much technical
controversy raised by the work of Allegretto et al (2011) and
Dube et al (2010), well summarised in the recent work by
Neumark et al (2014). The key problem is how to specify
control groups, whether by allowing for state-specific trends, or
by using contiguous states, which need not be good controls
since cross-border counties might not experience the same
shocks. Still, Neumark et al’s exhaustive analysis (2014, p627)
concludes that, when the time trends are correctly specified, the
elasticity of teen employment to the minimum wage remains in
or near the -0.1 to -0.2 range. Elasticity of employment in the
restaurant sector is lower, but still negative and significant at
around -0.05 or -0.06 (2014, p644). Thus the adverse effect
remains.
We cannot leave US minimum wage research without
mentioning the famous but weak Card and Krueger (1995)
studies of the response of fast-food restaurant employment to
increases in minimum wages. The best-known of these studies is
the contrast of New Jersey with Pennsylvania (which had no
increase in the minimum wage). This research is the basis for
stating that the conventional economic view that minimum
wages cause unemployment is a “myth”. But the New Jersey
versus Pennsylvania study is only based on 4 datapoints. The
fact that there are many restaurants in the 4 samples (New
Jersey before and after, and the control, Pennsylvania before
and after) is no help since the same minimum wage regime
applies in each. It is also worth noting that again we have the
restaurant sector, which is sheltered from international
competition, and so should have smaller employment reactions.
The work is sold as “a powerful new challenge to the
conventional view”, but it is misleading.
The evidence from South Africa shows what happens when
minimum wages really go wrong. South Africa under white
control, before 1994, had what it described as a “civilised
labour policy” aiming to favour white employment (Van der
Horst 1942, 250; also Siebert 1986). A pillar of this policy was
high minimum wages and extended collective agreements which
meant that only white workers, who were generally better
educated than non-white workers, could gain employment.
Minimum wages were thus used as a weapon against the
majority. The higher costs that resulted were not so much of a
problem when it came to employment because tariff barriers
prevented imports competing with domestic businesses. The
high minimum wage system continues to this day with extended
collective agreements in particular supporting a strongly
unionised African labour elite (Schultz 1998). For example, a
union worker in manufacturing receives 70% more than a non-
union worker (Schultz 1998, p700). The system has since been
extended to agriculture and domestic service. In agriculture the
pay increase has been large (Bhorat et all 2012), 17%, and
employment has contracted considerably, by 14%. In domestic
service, again protected from international competition, the
effects might not have been so bad (Dinkelman 2012, Hertz
2005), but only 25% of households appear to comply. Thus, we
see a policy originally designed to hurt African workers is now
being carried forward by African politicians and unions
themselves, and still hurting African workers.
Finally, let us consider the evidence from international cross-
country panels. This research design gives the most variation in
minimum wages, and thus helps create more robust studies.
Negative employment effects from minimum wages are clear in
all the studies. Admittedly there are some difficulties of
comparability. In particular, countries such as Germany, Italy,
Denmark and Sweden have no national minimum wage as such,
but use legally enforceable extended collective agreements.
Still, such agreements are effective minima (see below). There
is also the difficulty of allowing for widely different welfare
regimes, and these studies typically use the OECD’s index of
gross benefit replacement rates which leaves out housing
benefit that are important in the UK[footnoteRef:4]. However,
hopefully the gross replacement rates capture the trends, and in
any case the studies all control for country and time fixed
effects. [4: Hence Addison and Ozturk’s (2012, Table 2b)
replacement rate for the UK averages only 20%, much lower
than the actual 60% shown in Table 1 above.]
Neumark and Wascher (2004) provide the first comprehensive
treatment, analysing 17 OECD countries over the period 1975-
2000. Their main finding (2004, p243) is that the minimum
wage elasticity of teenage (15-19) employment is significantly
negative, in the -0.2 to -0.4 range. More recently there have
been OECD-based international studies by Dolton and
Bondiabene (2012) of youth employment, and Addison and
Ozturk (2012) of female employment. Dolton and Bondiabene
(2012) also find a large negative effect of minimum wages for
youth employment, with an elasticity of -0.3 to -0.4, most of
this result coming in recession as might be expected. Addison
and Ozturk (2012, Table 4) find a negative effect for the adult
female employment-to-population rate, with an elasticity of -
0.14 in the short run, and more in the long run when lagged
effects are taken into account. Interestingly, there is an
indication in this study (2012, Table 7) that the elasticity is
larger (-0.34) in countries and time periods when employment
protection law (EPL) is strict, as we would expect (see below).
Thus, there is an unambiguous picture of strong negative
minimum wage effects on lower-productivity groups in the
international panel-based literature, which provides arguably
the best foundation for research.
Collectively set minimum wages
Collectively set minimum wages arise when a collective
agreement is extended by law to third parties within an industry
or sector. A detailed set of minimum wages (and conditions)
covering many job types and levels is thereby established for
the industry or sector. Martins (2014) shows how the process
works in the case of Portugal. Such extensions are the result of
so-called “erga omnes” (towards others) regulations, and have
the aim of reducing non-union low-wage competition. They are
common (see Murtin et al 2014) in countries where the unions
are politically powerful – for example, are part-funded or
privileged by the state as in Greece or France or South Africa –
but where local union power is low (again, France and
Greece[footnoteRef:5]). In these circumstances, unions have the
power to bring about these regulations and also need to, since
non-union firms are so prevalent. The picture is given in Table
5, where we see that France, Spain, Portugal, Germany and Italy
all have high use of extensions arrangements. The important
point is that erga omnes regulations enable the setting of
detailed minimum wage floors, floors that are determined by big
business and labour in the capital cities – Athens, Rome, Paris –
with little concern for conditions in the provinces. Hence, a
straitjacket of minimum wages is thrown over the country. [5:
The UK used to have an erga omnes arrangement for unions to
petition for extension of their agreements, but Thatcher
dismantled it (see Addison and Siebert 2000) with the 1980
Employment Act. The “fair wages resolution” requiring
government contractors to observe terms no less favourable than
those obtaining under collective agreements was also dropped at
this time.]
Research on this type of minimum wage setting builds on the
literature of union power raising unemployment, which of
course has long been controversial because of the many factors
that influence unemployment. Steven Nickell’s (1997) famous
study of unemployment in OECD countries in the 1980s and
1990s shows union agreement coverage strongly raising
unemployment, but his “bargaining coordination” variable
washes out this effect, suggesting that cooperation between the
two sides of industry (corporatism) could engender responsible
unionism. Recent work on these lines is reported in the
OECD’s (2011b, p152) study of inequality using the OECD
panel of countries over 1984-2007. Here there is shown to be a
well-determined negative effect of collective bargaining
coverage on employment rates. High tax rates and employment
protection legislation hurt too. The most recent work using the
OECD panel is by Murtin et al (2014) with a more extensive
model, this time of unemployment. Their main innovation is to
use collective agreement coverage extension, as shown in Table
5, which they find interacts with taxes (also shown in Table 5)
to raise unemployment. Their minimum wage variable also
raises unemployment, again more so when taxes are high.
These interaction results can be explained with the aid of Figure
3. Again we have the conventional demand (D) and supply (S)
curves for unskilled labour, and start with a no-tax equilibrium
at E1. Now, assume a tax is imposed, so that the net demand
curve for labour shifts inwards to D|net tax as shown. Without
the minimum wage or collective agreement floor, the new
equilibrium would be at E2 with a lower wage, and less
employment (but no disequilibrium unemployment). However, if
there is a wage floor, the wage cannot fall so much, and the
employment fall to B is greater, as shown. At B there is also
disequilibrium unemployment. Therefore, according to this
simple model a rise in tax sweeps more into the minimum wage
and extended collective agreement net, causing unemployment.
The empirical results support this theoretical observation.
There are also instructive results from two country case studies
of Portugal and Greece involving extended agreements. As can
be seen from Table 5, both of these countries have used such
agreements extensively, though they are now restricted by
recent debt bailout agreements[footnoteRef:6]. Martins’ (2014)
analysis of Portugal over 2007-11 links unemployment to
extensions of agreements to non-parties, and shows that average
employment levels in affected sectors drop by 2% in the four
months following extensions, as firms stop hiring, and close
down. Since the wage increase is 2% to 4%, the implied
elasticity is between -0.5 and -1 (Martins 2014, 14). Peripheral
employment of temporary workers and sub-contractors
meanwhile increases, as we would expect. This temporary
worker result is the same as that for the Greek study
(Anagnostopoulos and Siebert 2013), based on a survey of 200
provincial firms, which finds that low-paying firms, near the
minimum, are more likely to employ temporary workers. The
Greek study also shows that these effects persist even though
many Greek firms do not in fact pay the minimum they remain
small so as to avoid the attentions of the labour inspectorate.
The minimum wage and extended collective agreements coupled
with high taxes thus not only reduce employment, but also push
firms to be too small[footnoteRef:7]. [6: In Greece for example
(see Commission 2014 p49 and LABREF database), the
government in 2011 and 2012 agreed to reduce minimum pay
rates by 22% (32% for young people). It also agreed to suspend
extension of occupational and sector collective agreements, and
to allow firm-level agreements which could be less favourable
than the sector-level agreement. According to IndustriALL
(2014) measures such as this caused Greek sector agreements to
fall from 65 to 14 in 2013, and in Portugal (Martins 2014),
coverage fell from 1.8 million in 2008 to 290,000 in 2012.] [7:
Thus in Greece and Portugal firms are too small, with only 5%
employing more than 10 people, compared to an OECD average
of 15% employing more than 10 (see OECD, 2011c).
Alternatively, if policing of the extended agreements is
effective, as in South Africa, small firms can be prevented from
growing enough (see Magruder 2012). The point is, regulation
breeds regulation.]
Conclusions and thoughts on real help for the unskilled
Mnimum wages do have adverse employment effects broadly in
line with conventional economic models. UK studies generally
find small effects, but the UK environment is poorly suited to
measure such effects given the changes in welfare benefits, and
the lack of regional variation. Matters become clearer when we
turn to more suitable empirical settings which provide clear
evidence of an adverse effects of minimum wages on
employment.
Better ways to help the poor involve raising skills or, in the
shorter term before such policies take meaningful effect, the
provision of wage subsidies through the welfare system. When
it comes to raising skills, the family is crucial, together with
education. In fact, Table 6 shows that comparable countries all
have difficulties with families in poor circumstances, so the UK
is not alone. Admittedly, the first two rows show that the UK
has exceptionally high numbers of children in single parent and
workless households (see Kristian Niemietz 2012). Yet while
Italy does best on this criterion, as can be seen, it lags
otherwise. The intergenerational earnings correlation is 0.48 in
the UK which is high[footnoteRef:8], but no worse than in Italy
or the US. Moreover, inequality in disposable household
incomes, as measured by the Gini coefficient, is broadly similar
at around 0.30 to 0.34 in all the countries. Only the US stands
out as particularly unequal, but this result is to be expected
since the US is much larger and more heterogeneous. [8: Here
we correlate the incomes of fathers and sons. A low correlation
as in Germany, 0.32, is better because it shows that good
parental circumstances have less effect in improving the child’s
life chances than in the UK which has a much higher
correlation.]
Furthermore, taking adult language proficiency which is an
important measure of skill, we see a distinct gradient according
to family background, as is to be expected. Individuals from
advantaged backgrounds (having at least one parent with a
university degree) score about 1 point higher on a 1 to 5 scale
than the less advantaged. All the comparator countries have an
almost exactly similar effect, which points once again to the
fact that this problem is deep-seated. Encouragement of stable
families and better, less unionised and more competitive school
systems is difficult, but they are important policy priorities.
High welfare simply makes matters worse in the long term, as
well described by Charles Murray (1984, 2012).
A quick and well-targeted way of helping the working poor is
by subsidising low paid work, a policy which contradicts the
minimum wage. People have their earnings topped up by the tax
payer, and are therefore prepared to work for less, which
expands their job opportunities. In fact, such a policy has been
in place in the UK ever since 1999 when the Working Families
Tax Credit was introduced (Azhmat 2006), modelled on the US
Earned Income Tax Credit, and since expanded with Working
Tax Credit (see Bourne and Shackleton 2014). Figure 4 shows
how the policy works by reducing the wage that the employer
pays from W* to WL. The equilibrium on the original demand
curve moves to point A, to which is added the subsidy, and the
worker receives the higher gross wage, WH.= WL+SUB. It is
important that the wage the employer pays is allowed to fall,
though, and if the minimum wage prevents this fall, the policy
will not work, and we remain at C. In a sense, the employer has
to be paid some of the subsidy and his/her profits will increase
which has disturbed some commentators (e.g. Gregg et al 2012).
However, the result is more jobs which is what we want.
Tax credits conditional on work currently encourage about 2.5
million workers to work (see Browne and Hood 2012), but they
only account for about 5% of the amount paid out to working
age welfare recipients, and are dwarfed in particular by child
tax credits and housing benefits. Reform is needed to make
working tax credits more important (see Bourne and Shackleton
2014). This said, the way they lower wages (see Azmat 2006
and Hotz and Scholz 2000) is exactly as predicted by our
conventional labour market analysis.
In conclusion, there is no need for analysts (e.g. Holmlund
2014, or Schmitt 2013) to worry about “discernible effects" of
minimum wages on employment. The effects are discernible,
when properly measured. Hence it is indeed probable that the
UK’s dismal youth labour market performance since 1999 is
partly attributable to the imposition of the minimum wage –
interacting with high tax rates. This is also the case with the
poorly functioning youth labour markets of Portugal and
Greece, and others such as France and South Africa. Moreover,
the way in which more skilled workers displace the less skilled,
and temporary workers displace permanent workers is also in
line with conventional economic models. Obviously, in a
political world which denies productivity differences –
including skills, gender, age and disability
differences[footnoteRef:9] – the differential effects of minimum
wages are politically unwelcome This is all the more reason for
economists to stick to their guns and look for real, not fake,
ways to help the poor. [9: The disability pressure groups often
do the disabled no favours. For example, (LPC 2005 p124),
Mothercare for Children in Hospital Ltd (MCCH) cooed: “ the
minimum wage is a positive step to reducing stigma,
discrimination and workplace exploitation…it has acted as a
catalyst to change” etc etc. But Shaw Employment Services is
blunt: ”Both client and provider are finding that instead of
being more able to help the disabled achieve employment, the
Government, through the NMW, has inadvertently created the
first barrier” (LPC 2003, p105).]
References
Addison, J., M. Blackburn and C. Cotti (2012), “Labour Market
Outcomes: County-Level Estimates from the Restaurant-and-Bar
Sector”, British Journal of Industrial Relations, 50: 412-435.
Addison, J. and O. Ozturk (2012), “Minimum Wages, Labor
Market Institutions, and Female Employment: A Cross-Country
Analysis”, Industrial and Labor Relations Review, 65: 779-809.
Addison, J. and W. Stanley Siebert (1994), “Recent
Developments in Social Policy in the New European Union”,
Industrial and Labor Relations Review, 48:5-27.
Addison J and W. S. Siebert (2000), "Labor Market Reform in
the UK: from Thatcher to Blair", Journal of Private Enterprise,
15: 1-34.
Allegretto, S., A. Dube, and M. Reich. (2011), “Do Minimum
Wages Really Reduce Teen Employment? Accounting for
heterogeneity and selectivity in state panel data. Industrial
Relations50: 205–40.
Azmat, G. (2006), “The Incidence of an Earned Income Tax
Credit: Evaluating the Impact on Wages in the UK”, London
School of Economics, CEP Discussion Paper 724.
Anagnostopoulos A. and W. S. Siebert (2012), “The impact of
Greek labour market regulation on temporary and family
employment - Evidence from a new survey”, IZA Discussion
Paper 6504.
Baker, M., D. Benjamin and S. Stanger (1999). “The Highs and
Lows of the Minimum Wage Effect: A Time-Series Cross-
Section Study of the Canadian Law”, Journal of Labor
Economics, 17:18-50.
Baum, C. (2006), An Introduction to Modern Econometrics
Using Stata, College Station, Texas: Stata Press.
Bhorat, H., R. Kanbur and B. Stanwix (2013), “Estimating the
Impact of Minimum Wages on Employment, Wages and
Nonwage Benefits: The Case of Agriculture in South Africa”,
Cornell University, School of Applied Economics and
Management, WP 2013-05.
Bourne, R. and J. Shackleton (2014), “The Minimum Wage:
Silver Bullet or Poisoned Chalice”, Institute of Economic
Affairs Briefing 14.01.
Brown J. and A. Hood (2012), A Survey of the UK Benefit
System, IFS Briefing Note BN13, London: Institute for Fiscal
Studies.
Campolieti, M., M. Gunderson and B. Lee (2014), “Minimum
Wage Effects On Permanent Versus Temporary Minimum Wage
Employment”, Contemporary Economic Policy, 32: 578-591.
Card, D., and A. Krueger (1995). Myth and Measurement: the
New Economics of the Minimum wage, Princeton: Princeton
University Press.
Commission (2006), Green Paper—Modernising labour law to
meet the challenges of the 21st century, Brussels 22.11.2006
COM(2006) 708 final.
Commission (2014), “The Second Economic Adjustment
Programme for Greece”, Occasional Papers, No. 192, April,
Brussels: Directorate-General for Economic and Financial
Affairs .
Corak, M., (2013), Income Inequality, Equality of Opportunity,
and Intergenerational Mobility, Journal of Economic
Perspectives, 27: 79-102.
Cox, J. and R. Oaxaca (1982), ‘The political economy of
minimum wage legislation”, Economic Inquiry, 20: 533-50.
Dickens, R., R. Riley and D. Wilkinson, (2012), “Re-examining
the Impact of the National Minimum Wage on Earnings,
Employment and Hours: the Importance of Recession and Firm
Size”, University of Sussex and National Institute of Economic
and Social Research.
http://www.sheffield.ac.uk/polopoly_fs/1.247213!/file/E1_riley.
pdf
Dinkelman T. and V. Ranchod (2012), “Evidence on the impact
of minimum wage laws in an informal sector: Domestic workers
in South Africa”, Journal of Development Economics, 99: 27-
45.
Dolton, Peter and Chiara Bondibene (2012), “The International
Experience of Minimum Wages in an Economic Downturn”,
Economic Policy, 27: 99-142.
Dube, A., T. Lester, and M. Reich. (2010), Minimum Wage
Effects Across State Borders: Estimates using contiguous
counties. Review of Economics and Statistics92: 945–64.
Fang, T. and M. Gunderson (2009), “Minimum Wage Impacts on
Older Workers: Longitudinal Estimates from Canada”, British
Journal of Industrial Relations, 47: 371-87.
Fang T., and C. Lin (2013), “Minimum Wages and Employment
in China”, IZA Discussion Paper 7813.
Godfrey, S., J. Theron and M. Visser (2007), The State of
Collective Bargaining in South Africa, UCT: Development
Policy Research Unit Research Paper 07/130
Gorry, A. (2013), “Minimum wages and youth unemployment”,
European Economic Review 64: 57-75.
Gregg, P., A. Hurrell and M. Whittaker (2012), Creditworthy –
Assessing the Impact of Tax Credits, London: Resolution
Foundation.
Hertz, T. (2005), “The Effect of Minimum Wages on the
Employment and Earnings of South Africa's Domestic Service
Workers, Upjohn Institute Working Paper 05-120.
Holmlund, B. (2014), “What do labor market institutions do?”,
Labour Economics 30: 62-69.
Hotz, V. and J. Scholtz (2000), “Not Perfect, but Still Pretty
Good: The EITC and Other Policies to Support the US Low-
Wage Labour Market”, OECD Economic Studies 31.
IndustriALL (2014), “Negotiating our future!”, Collective
Bargaining and Social Policy Conference, Vienna,
http://www.industriall-
europe.eu/committees/CB/2014/Increasing%20cover%20rate-
EN.pdf
Kay L. (2010), Escaping the Poverty Trap, London: Policy
Exchange.
Krugman, P. (1994), “Past and Prospective Causes of High
Unemployment”, Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City,
http://www.kc.frb.org/publicat/econrev/pdf/4q94krug.pdf
Leonard, M., T. Stanley and H. Doucouliagos (2014), “Does the
UK MinimumWage Reduce Employment? A Meta-Regression
Analysis”, British Journal of Industrial Relations, 52: 499-520.
Living Wage Commission (2014), Work That Pays, London:
Joseph Rowntree Trust.
LPC (2014), Low Pay Commission Report 2014, Cm 8816,
London: Low Pay Commission.
LPC (2005), Low Pay Commission Report 2005, Cm 6475,
London: Low Pay Commission.
LPC (2003), Low Pay Commission Report 2003 – Building on
Success, London: Low Pay Commission.
LPC (2001), The National Minimum Wage – Making a
Difference, Volume 1, Cm 5075, London: Low Pay Commission.
Magruder, J (2013), “Can Minimum Wages Cause a Big Push?
Evidence from Indonesia”, Journal of Development Economics,
100: 48-62.
Magruder (2012), High Unemployment Yet Few Small Firms:
The Role of Centralized Bargaining in South Africa”, American
Economic Journal: Applied Economics, 4: 138-166.
Manning A. (2013), “Minimum Wages: A View from the UK”,
Perspektiven der Wirtschaftspolitik, 14: 57–66.
Martins, P. (2014) “30,000 Minimum Wages: The Economic
Effects of Collective Bargaining Extensions”, IZA Discussion
Paper 8540.
Murray C. (1984), Losing Ground: American Social Policy
1950-1980, New York: Basic Books.
Murray C. (2012), Coming Apart: The State of Whate America
1960-2010, New York: Crown Forum.
Murtin, F., A. de Serres and A. Hijzen (2014), “Unemployment
and the coverage extension of collective wag eagreements”,
European Economic Review, 71: 52-66.
Neumark, D., J. Salas and W. Wascher (2014), “Revisiting the
Minimum Wage-Employment Debate: Throwing Out the Baby
with the Bathwater?”, Industrial and Labor Relations Review,
67 (supplement): 608-48.
Neumark, D. and W. Wascher (2008), “Minimum Wages and
Low-Wage Workers: How Well Does Reality Match the
Rhetoric?”, Minnesota Law Review, 92: 1296-1316.
Neumark, D., and W.Wascher, 2004. “Minimum Wages, Labor
Market Institutions and Youth Unemployment: A Cross-
National Analysis”, Industrial and Labor Relations Review, 57:
223-48.
Nickell, S. (1997), “Unemployment and Labor Market
Rigidities: Europe versus North America”, Journal of Economic
Perspectives, 11: 55-74.
Riley, R. (2013), “Modelling Demand for Low Skilled/Low Paid
Labour: Exploring The Employment Trade-Offs of a Living
Wage”, NIESR Discussion Paper 404
Niemietz, K. (2012), Redefining the Poverty Debate, London:
Institute of Economic Affairs.
OECD (2014), Education at a Glance 2014: OECD Indicators,
OECD Publishing, http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/eag-2014-en
OECD (2011), Doing Better for Families Paris: OECD
Publishing DOI:10.1787/9789264098732-en
OECD (2011), Divided We Stand: Why Inequality Keeps
Rising, Paris: OECD Publishing.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/9789264119536-en
Sen, A., K. Rybzynski and C. Van De Waal (2011), “Teen
Employment, Poverty, and the Minimum Wage: Evidence from
Canada”, Labour Economics, 18: 36-47
Schmitt, J. (2013). “Why Does the Minimum Wage Have No
Discernible Effect on Employment?”, Washington: Center for
Economic and Policy Research
Schultz, T. and G. Mwabu (1998), “Labor Unions and the
Distribution of Wages and Employment in South Africa”,
Industrial and Labor Relations Review, 51: 680-703.
Siebert W. S. (2014), “The Living Wage”, Economic Affairs
Magazine, Summer: 18-21.
Siebert W. S. (2013), “The Wage Flaw – Why Minimum Pay
Isn’t Working”, Economic Affairs Magazine, Summer: 4-7.
Siebert, W. S. (1986), “Restrictive Practices in South Africa’s
Labour Market”, Economic Affairs, October-November: 26-29.
Van der Horst, S. (1942), Native Labour in South Africa,
London: Frank Cass.
Visser J. (2013), Wage Bargaining Institutions - from crisis to
crisis, Brussels, Directorate-General for Economic and
Financial Affairs: Economic Papers 488.
Wang, J. and M. Gunderson (2012), “Minimum wage effects on
employment and wages: dif-in-dif estimates from eastern
China”, International Journal of Manpower, 33: 860-876.
Table 1: Net replacement rates over 60 Months unemployment
France
Germany
United States
UK
No child
2 child
No child
2 child
No child
2 child
No child
2 child
2001
60.3
70.3
59.6
73.5
15.2
43.0
55.0
64.9
2012
53.6
63.2
49.9
70.4
24.8
42.8
51.0
72.4
Change 2012-2001
-6.7
-7.1
-9.7
-3.0
9.6
-0.2
-4.0
7.5
Source: OECD Benefits and Wages:
Statisticshttp://www.oecd.org/els/benefitsandwagesstatistics.ht
m (NRR_Over5years_EN)
Notes: Replacement rates are calculated based on incomes after
any tax and social security contributions have been deducted,
and any cash benefits received. Family qualifies for cash
housing assistance and social assistance "top ups". The figures
give unweighted averages relative to full-time earnings levels of
67% and 100% of average worker earnings. (Prior to 2001 only
gross rates not including housing assistance are available.)
Table 2: Adverse Changes in Employment for Unskilled
Workers
Labourforce participation rate (% of the population in each
group)
All working age
No qualific-ations
Disabled people
18-20 yrs old
16-24 yrs old
France
15-24
2000
71.7
50.8
37.7
61.2
69.7
35.6
2013
71.6
42.6
42.1
47.0
61.7
37.6
Change 2013-2000
-0.1
-8.2
4.4
-14.2
-8.0
2.0
Sources: Commission (2014, Table 2.11), and OECD
Employment Outlook (2014)
Table 3: NEETs – Country Trends
(% of 15-19 year olds not in education, employment or training)
France
Germany
Italy
United States
UK
OECD average
1997
2.9
5.0
15.2
7.1
8.0
9.2
2012
6.9
3.0
12.0
7.7
9.5
7.6
Change 2012-1997
4.0
-2.0
-3.2
0.6
1.5
-1.6
Sources: OECD Education at a Glance (2014), Chart C5.3, and
OECD Doing Better for Families (2011), Figure 1.15
Table 4: Firm Size and Employment, UK 2009
Number - Private Sector, 2009 (including pub corps and
nationalised bodies)
Enterprises (000)
Employees (mill.)
Enterprises. without employees
3620
0
Enterprises with employees
1220
18.2
Enterprise sizes:
1-4
795
1.8
5-49
390
4.6
50-249
30
2.6
250-499
3
1.0
500 or more
3
8.1
MEMO
Central and local govt
5
5.4
Non-profit
84
1.9
Source: BIS, Enterprise Directorate, 2010,
http://stats.bis.gov.uk/ed/sme/SMEStats2009.xls#'UK Whole
Economy'!A1
Notes: An enterprise is the smallest group of legal units which
has autonomy. It is based on the Interdepartmental Business
Register (IDBR) formed from VAT or PAYE records collected
by HMRC. Since the VAT threshold (£67k in 09) excludes small
firms, estimates of their numbers are then added using
Labourforce Survey figures of numbers of self-employed
(4.1m). Private households and temp agencies are excluded..
There is no lower bound for inclusion as an enterprise, hence
the smallest amount of enterprise activity counts – hence there
are many "no employee" enterprises which have only working
proprietors in the business. “Employees” have a contract of
employment, and include part-timers. Working proprietors are
self employed (but working directors of companies are counted
as employees).
Table 5: Collectively Set Minimum Wages, early 2000s
Can
Den
Fra
Ger
Gre
Ita
Nor
Por
SA
Spain
Swe
UK
US
Coverage* extension
4
0
79
48
30
46
15
49
10
57
1
9
4
Use of erga omnes clauses
No
No
High
High
High
High
Some
High
Some
High
No
No
No
Union density
31
75
9
28
30
34
56
25
25
15
81
34
14
Govt rev % GDP
40
55
50
45
38
47
57
40
27
36
54
40
31
Sources: Murtins et al (2014), Industriall Global Union (2014)
http://www.industriall-
europe.eu/committees/CB/2014/Increasing%20cover%20rate-
EN.pdf; Visser (2013), Godfrey (2007), OECD Government at a
Glance (2013, Table 3.11.
Notes: * coverage extension measured as collective agreement
coverage minus percentage unionisation
Table 6: Inequalities – Country Comparisons
France
Germany
Italy
United States
UK
% children (0-18) in single-parent households, 2007a
14
15
10
22
26
% children (0-14) living in jobless households, 2011b
10
7
8
8
19
Intergenerational earnings correlation, late 90sc
0.40
0.32
0.49
0.50
0.48
Gini coefficient of inequality of household disposable incomed
0.29
0.30
0.33
0.37
0.34
Average adult literacy proficiency levele
Both parents<upper secondary educ.
2.0
1.8
1.9
1.8
2.1
At least one parent with tertiary educ.
3.0
2.8
2.7
2.9
3.1
Sources: a OECD Doing Better for Families (2011) Table 1.1; b
OECD Doing Better for Families (2011) Table LMF1.1.A; c
Corak (2013, p82); d OECD Divided We Stand (2011), Fig 6.1.
(income is household income, corrected for household size – the
Gini coefficient varies between 0 for perfect equality, and 1 for
perfect inequality); e OECD Education at a Glance (2014, Chart
A4.4) (literacy score is from the OECD programme for
International Assessment of Adult Competencies, with
proficiency graded from worst (1) to best (5)).
(
D
S
Welfare benefits floor
W*
A
B
Unskilled Labour
E
Minimum wage floor
)
Figure 1: Welfare benefits confound minimum wage
employment effects
Figure 2: Effects of the minimum wage on earnings - 1998 and
1999 compared
Source: Low Pay Commission Report 2000, p19
(
Unskilled Labour
Minimum wage or collective
agreement
floor
D|
gross
S
W*
E
2
B
E
1
D|
net
tax
TAX
)
Figure 3: Minimum wage magnifies disemployment effects of
tax
(
Unskilled Labour
W*
SUB
D|
gross
D|
plus
subsidy
S
W*
W
L
W
H
B
A
Minimum wage or collective
agreement
floor
C
)
Figure 4: Subsidising work
5
Leading Change
Leading Change
Carlos Ghosen was named CEO of Nissan took over the Renault
company in April of 2005. The new position would continue to
head Nissan as well as Renault. Ghosen was well known for his
ability to turn struggling companies into profit driven thriving
businesses and that was the hope of the new assignment with
Renault.
Issues
In March of 1999, the ninth carmaker in the world asked Carlos
Ghosen to lead as its CEO after a failed merger with Volvo.
Nissans strength in product design and manufacturing and
Renaults engineering quality made the merger all the more
necessary. Renault would help with international expansions
and Nissan would get rid of its short-term troubles of poor
production portfolio and its diminished brand value.
As one of the youngest to head companies of this size, Ghosn
knew he had to make an impact, for the Japanese were not
accustomed to a dictatorship type of leadership. Therefore, he
knew dictating his expectations could lead to low morale, and if
too lenient, it could slow change. Therefore, Ghosen brought
the need for urgency in operations by mobilizing them. Just as
Nissan’s employees were reluctant to except failures and
blamed other departments or economic changes on most of the
problems, which resulted in the lack of urgency and the resolve
to just live with the problems. Ghosen believed that human
tendency is to resist change and anything new of different from
the status quo. However, he belied by excepting changes, people
will be stronger, because they would have a better
understanding of the differences and find ways to discover the
root cause of the issues. Proposed
Solution
s
Ghosen formed Cross-function teams with employees being
directly involved in the process. Doing so helped Ghosen
explain his plans and gain acceptance more easily. In these
cross-functional teams, the employees were asked to look
beyond their responsibilities, and obtain a better understanding
of other departments. Once the teams were in place it became
much easier for the employees to see and own responsibility
whenever something went wrong.
Just after appointing the teams, they were asked to submit their
plans to achieve the maximum output in each of the areas. By
listening to the employees and asking their opinions in the
reform process, was monumental in the way Ghosen lead his
vision for reform. He avoided impersonal meetings and stressed
the importance of face-to-face communications.
Once both companies became one, Ghosn choose to promote
Transparency, Performance, and Value. Ghosn believed that
blending the strengths of the employees at each of the
companies, innovation excellence of the French and the
dedication towards the manufacturing of the Japanese, which
created synergy in purchasing, manufacturing, information
systems and platform sharing, but also maintained both
companies autonomy by keeping their own brand identities and
corporations.
Ghosn’s goal was to making the company recognizable by the
consumer as one of the best automakers in quality, value,
service and generate a total operating profit among all other
leading automakers by keeping a high profit margin and
continued upward growth. Renault took an equity stake in
Nissan with the understanding that Nissan would have the same
opertunity at a later time. This would enhance both Renault and
Nissan’s performance by creating a community interest and
cross shareholdings.Barriers to Change/ Emotional Bonds
The differences in culture between the French and Japanese
could have been very difficult, however Ghosn kept an open
mind focusing on the economic benefits and the turnaround of
the company’s. Goshn had to make tough changes such as
haying off more than 21,000 people and closing five factories in
order to increase Nissans profit margin. He also changed the
policy of the lifetime employment and hired more women,
which both were frowned upon. Goshn also demanded at least
20% savings from suppliers over a 3-year time period and the
ability to use global contractors.
Personal reflection
I think Goshn took whatever measures necessary to get both
companies producing at profitable pace and I think his decisions
on were based on that fact, which proved profitable in the end.
Conclusion
The commitments of the Nissan Revival Plan had been met one
year prior to its expected schedule, and the launch of new
models was created at a very high rate. Nissans profitability
contributed to Renault’s net income and higher profitability and
global presence. The President of Nissan was concerned about
the complacent nature of Nissan because of poor markets.
However, he also expected more flexibility to ensure employees
work closer to the consumer’s needs.
References
Spector, B. (2013). Implementing organizational change:
Theory into practice (3rd ed.). Upper Saddle River, NJ: Prentice
Hall
Leading Change 4
Copyright © 2014 Cengage Learning
*
*
Chapter 17
The Economics of Labour Markets
2.bin
Copyright © 2014 Cengage Learning
THE MARKET FOR THE FACTORS OF PRODUCTIONFactors
of production are the inputs used to produce goods and services.
The demand for a factor of production is a derived demand.A
firm’s demand for a factor of production is derived from its
decision to supply a good in another market.
Copyright © 2014 Cengage Learning
THE DEMAND FOR LABOURLabour markets, like other
markets in the economy, are governed by the forces of supply
and demand.Most labour services, rather than being final goods
ready to be enjoyed by consumers, are inputs into the
production of other goods.
Copyright © 2014 Cengage Learning
The Production Function and the Marginal Product of Labour
The production function illustrates the relationship between the
quantity of inputs used and the quantity of output of a good.
Copyright © 2014 Cengage Learning
Table 1 How the Competitive Firm Decides How Much Labour
to Hire
Copyright©2014 Cengage
Copyright © 2014 Cengage Learning
Figure 1 The Production Function
Quantity of
Apple Pickers
0
Quantity
of Apples
300
280
240
180
100
1
2
3
4
5
Copyright©2014 Cengage
Production
function
Copyright © 2014 Cengage Learning
The Production Function and the Marginal Product of Labour
The marginal product of labour is the increase in the amount of
output from an additional unit of labour.
MPL = (Q2 – Q1)/(L2 – L1)
Copyright © 2014 Cengage Learning
The Production Function and the Marginal Product of
LabourDiminishing Marginal Product of Labour
As the number of workers increases, the marginal product of
labour declines.
As more and more workers are hired, each additional worker
contributes less to production than the prior one.
The production function becomes flatter as the number of
workers rises.
This property is called diminishing marginal product.
Copyright © 2014 Cengage Learning
The Production Function and the Marginal Product of
LabourDiminishing marginal product refers to the property
whereby the marginal product of an input declines as the
quantity of the input increases.
Copyright © 2014 Cengage Learning
Figure 1 The Production Function
Quantity of
Apple Pickers
0
Quantity
of Apples
300
280
240
180
100
1
2
3
4
5
Copyright©2014 Cengage
Production
function
Copyright © 2014 Cengage Learning
The Value of the Marginal Product and the Demand for
LabourThe value of the marginal product is the marginal
product of the input multiplied by the market price of the
output.
Copyright © 2014 Cengage Learning
The Value of the Marginal Product and the Demand for Labour
The value of the marginal product (also known as marginal
revenue product) is measured as a money cost.It diminishes as
the number of workers rises because the market price of the
good is constant.
Copyright © 2014 Cengage Learning
The Value of the Marginal Product and the Demand for
LabourTo maximize profit, the competitive, profit-maximizing
firm hires workers up to the point where the value of the
marginal product of labour equals the wage.
VMPL = Wage
Copyright © 2014 Cengage Learning
The Value of the Marginal Product and the Demand for
LabourThe value of marginal product curve is the labour
demand curve for a competitive, profit-maximizing firm.
Copyright © 2014 Cengage Learning
Figure 2 The Value of the Marginal Product of Labour
0
Quantity of
Apple Pickers
0
Value
of the
Marginal
Product
Copyright©2014 Cengage
Value of marginal product
(demand curve for labour)
Market
wage
Profit-maximizing quantity
Copyright © 2014 Cengage Learning
Input Demand and Output Supply: Two Sides of the Same Coin
When a competitive firm hires labour up to the point at which
the value of the marginal product equals the wage, it also
produces up to the point at which the price equals the marginal
cost.
Copyright © 2014 Cengage Learning
What Causes the Labour Demand Curve to Shift?Output price.
A change in the price of the product:
An increase raises the value of the marginal product of labour
and increases the demand for labour.
A decrease lowers the value of the marginal product of labour
and decreases the demand for labour. Technological change.
Technological advance raises the marginal product of labour,
which in turn raises the value of the marginal product of labour.
Change in the supply of other factors.
Copyright © 2014 Cengage Learning
EQUILIBRIUM IN THE LABOUR MARKETThe wage adjusts
to balance the supply and demand for labour.The wage equals
the value of the marginal product of labour.
Copyright © 2014 Cengage Learning
Figure 4 Equilibrium in a Labour Market
Wage
(price of
labour)
0
Quantity of
labour
Copyright©2014 Cengage
Supply
Demand
Equilibrium
wage,
W
Equilibrium
employment,
L
Copyright © 2014 Cengage Learning
EQUILIBRIUM IN THE LABOUR MARKETLabour supply and
labour demand determine the equilibrium wage.Shifts in the
supply or demand curve for labour cause the equilibrium wage
to change.
Copyright © 2014 Cengage Learning
Shifts in Labour SupplyAn increase in the supply of labour :
Results in a surplus of labour.
Puts downward pressure on wages.
Makes it profitable for firms to hire more workers.
Results in diminishing marginal product.
Lowers the value of the marginal product.
Gives a new equilibrium.
Copyright © 2014 Cengage Learning
Figure 6 A Shift in Labour Supply
Wage
(price of
labour)
0
Quantity of
labour
Copyright©2014 Cengage
Supply,
S
Demand
2. . . . reduces
the wage . . .
3. . . . and raises employment.
1. An increase in
labour supply . . .
S
W
L
W
L
Copyright © 2014 Cengage Learning
Shifts in Labour DemandAn increase in the demand for labour :
Makes it profitable for firms to hire more workers.
Puts upward pressure on wages.
Raises the value of the marginal product.
Gives a new equilibrium.
Copyright © 2014 Cengage Learning
Figure 7 A Shift in Labour Demand
Wage
(price of
labour)
0
Quantity of
labour
Copyright©2014 Cengage
Supply
Demand,
D
2. . . . increases
the wage . . .
3. . . . and increases employment.
D
W
L
W
L
1. An increase in
labour demand . . .
Copyright © 2014 Cengage Learning
MonopsonyDefinition of a monopsony: a market with a single
buyer. A monopsony is in many ways similar to a monopoly.
A monopsony employer will take into account that fact that the
supply curve for labour represents the average cost of labour.
(See figure 8)
The monopsony will employ fewer workers and at a lower rate.
Copyright © 2014 Cengage Learning
Figure 8 The Wage Rate and Employment Level in a Monopsony
Copyright©2014 Cengage
Copyright © 2014 Cengage Learning
WAGE DIFFERENTIALSWhat causes earnings to vary?
Wages are governed by labour supply and labour demand.
Labour demand reflects the marginal productivity of labour.
In equilibrium, each worker is paid the value of his or her
marginal contribution to the economy’s production of goods and
services.
Copyright © 2014 Cengage Learning
WAGE DIFFERENTIALSCauses
Compensating differentials
Human capital
Ability, effort, and chance
Signalling
The superstar phenomenon
Copyright © 2014 Cengage Learning
1. Compensating Differentials
Compensating differential refers to a difference in wages that
arises from non-monetary characteristics of different jobs.
Coal miners are paid more than others with similar levels of
education.
Night shift workers are paid more than day shift workers.
University professors are paid less than lawyers and doctors.
Copyright © 2014 Cengage Learning
2. Human Capital
Human capital is the accumulation of investments in people,
such as education and on-the-job training. The most important
type of human capital is education.
Firms are willing to pay more for highly educated workers
because highly educated workers have higher marginal products.
Copyright © 2014 Cengage Learning
3. Ability, Effort, and Chance People differ in their:
Physical and mental attributes. This will affect their
productivity level and therefore their wage.
Level of work effort. Those who work hard are more productive
and earn a higher wage.Chance also plays a role in determining
wages
Copyright © 2014 Cengage Learning
4. Alternative View of Education: SignallingFirms use
educational attainment as a way of sorting between high-ability
and low-ability workers.
It is rational for firms to interpret a university degree as a
signal of ability.
Copyright © 2014 Cengage Learning
5. The Superstar PhenomenonSuperstars arise in markets that
exhibit the following characteristics:
Every customer in the market wants to enjoy the good supplied
by the best producer.
The good is produced with a technology that makes it possible
for the best producer to supply every customer at a low cost.
Copyright © 2014 Cengage Learning
Above-Equilibrium Wages: Minimum-Wage Laws, Unions, and
Efficiency WagesWhy are some workers’ wages set above the
level that brings supply and demand into equilibrium?
Minimum wage laws
Market power of labour unions
Efficiency wages
Copyright © 2014 Cengage Learning
1. Minimum wagesThe market for labour looks like any other
market:
The equilibrium price is the wage and equilibrium quantity is
the labour hired.Introducing a minimum wage.
If the minimum wage is above the equilibrium wage in the
labour market, a surplus of labour will develop
(unemployment). (See figure 9)
The minimum wage will be a binding constraint only in markets
where equilibrium wages are low.
Thus, the minimum wage will have its greatest impact on the
market for teenagers and unskilled workers.
Copyright © 2014 Cengage Learning
Figure 9a How the Minimum Wage Affects the Labour Market
Copyright©2014 Cengage
Copyright © 2014 Cengage Learning
Figure 9b How the Minimum Wage Affects the Labour Market
Copyright©2014 Cengage
Copyright © 2014 Cengage Learning
1. Minimum wages Advocates for a minimum wage argue that
raising the standard of living of the working poor outweighs any
potential increase in unemployment. Opponents argue there are
better ways or combating poverty since:
A minimum wage raises unemployment
Some of those on a minimum wage are second earners in
households.
Those poor not in work do not gain the benefit.
Copyright © 2014 Cengage Learning
Figure 9a
Copyright©2014 Cengage
Copyright © 2014 Cengage Learning
2. The market Power of UnionsUnions often raise wages above
the level that would prevail without a union.A union is a worker
association that bargains with employers over wages and
working conditions.A strike refers to the organized withdrawal
of labour from a firm by a union.
Copyright © 2014 Cengage Learning
3. Efficiency Wages The theory of efficiency wages holds that a
firm can find it profitable to pay high wages because doing so
increases the productivity of its workers. High wages may:
Reduce worker turnover.
Increase worker effort.
Raise the quality of workers that apply for jobs at the firm.
Copyright © 2014 Cengage Learning
THE ECONOMICS OF DISCRIMINATION
Discrimination occurs when the marketplace offers different
opportunities to similar individuals who differ only by race,
ethnic group, sex, age, or other personal characteristics.
Copyright © 2014 Cengage Learning
Measuring Labour Market DiscriminationDiscrimination is
often measured by looking at the average wages of different
groups.However simply observing differences in wages among
broad groups—white and black, men and women—says little
about the prevalence of discrimination.
Copyright © 2014 Cengage Learning
Measuring Labour Market DiscriminationEven in a labour
market free of discrimination, different people have different
wages. People differ in the amount of human capital they have
and in the kinds of work they are willing and able to do.
Differences in average wages among groups in part reflect
differences in human capital and job characteristics so by
themselves they don’t say anything about how much labour
discrimination.
Copyright © 2014 Cengage Learning
Discrimination by EmployersFirms that do not discriminate
will:
Have lower labour costs when they hire the employees
discriminated against.
Tend to replace firms that discriminate.
Be more profitable than those firms that do
discriminate.Competitive markets tend to limit the impact of
discrimination on wages.
Copyright © 2014 Cengage Learning
Discrimination by Customers and GovernmentsAlthough the
profit motive is a strong force acting to eliminate
discriminatory wage differentials, there are limits to its
corrective abilities.
Customer preferences
Government policies
Copyright © 2014 Cengage Learning
Discrimination by Customers and GovernmentsCustomer
preferences:
If customers have discriminatory preferences, a competitive
market is consistent with a discriminatory wage differential.
This will happen when customers are willing to pay to maintain
the discriminatory practice.
Copyright © 2014 Cengage Learning
Discrimination by Customers and GovernmentsGovernment
policies:
When the government mandates discriminatory practices or
requires firms to discriminate, this may also lead to
discriminatory wage differentials.
Copyright © 2014 Cengage Learning
Becker’s Employer Taste Model People may have a ‘taste’ for
only working with certain groups of people. Those outside this
accepted group may end up being disadvantaged as a result.
Copyright © 2014 Cengage Learning
OTHER FACTORS OF PRODUCTION: LAND AND CAPITAL
Capital refers to the equipment and structures used to produce
goods and services.
The economy’s capital represents the accumulation of goods
produced in the past that are being used in the present to
produce new goods and services.
Copyright © 2014 Cengage Learning
OTHER FACTORS OF PRODUCTION: LAND AND
CAPITALPrices of Land and Capital.
The purchase price is what a person pays to own a factor of
production indefinitely.
The rental price is what a person pays to use a factor of
production for a limited period of time.The rental price of land
and the rental price of capital are determined by supply and
demand.
The firm increases the quantity hired until the value of the
factor’s marginal product equals the factor’s price.
Copyright © 2014 Cengage Learning
Figure 10 The Markets for Land and Capital
Quantity of
Land
0
Rental
Price of
Land
Quantity of
Capital
0
Rental
Price of
Capital
(a) The Market for Land
(b) The Market for Capital
Copyright©2014 Cengage
Demand
Supply
Demand
Supply
Q
P
P
Q
Copyright © 2014 Cengage Learning
Equilibrium in the Markets for Land and CapitalEach factor’s
rental price must equal the value of its marginal product. They
each earn the value of their marginal contribution to the
production process.
Copyright © 2014 Cengage Learning
Linkages among the Factors of ProductionFactors of production
are used together.
The marginal product of any one factor depends on the
quantities of all factors that are available.A change in the
supply of one factor alters the earnings of all the factors.A
change in earnings of any factor can be found by analysing the
impact of the event on the value of the marginal product of that
factor.
Copyright © 2014 Cengage Learning
ECONOMIC RENT
Economic rent is the amount a factor of production earns over
and above its transfer earnings.
Transfer earnings refers to the minimum payment required to
keep a factor of production in its current use. If economic rent
exists for any factor of production, the government could, in
theory, tax a portion of that rent without affecting the
employment of that factor in a particular use.
Copyright © 2014 Cengage Learning
Figure 11 Economic Rent
Copyright©2014 Cengage
Copyright © 2014 Cengage Learning
Summary
The three most important factors of production are labour, land,
and capital.
The demand for a factor, such as labour, is a derived demand
that comes from firms that use the factors to produce goods and
services.
Competitive, profit-maximizing firms hire each factor up to the
point at which the value of the marginal product of the factor
equals its price.
The supply of labour arises from individuals’ tradeoff between
work and leisure.
Copyright © 2014 Cengage Learning
Summary
An upward-sloping labour supply curve means that people
respond to an increase in the wage by enjoying less leisure and
working more hours.
The price paid to each factor adjusts to balance the supply and
demand for that factor.
Because factor demand reflects the value of the marginal
product of that factor, in equilibrium each factor is compensated
according to its marginal contribution to the production of
goods and services.
Because factors of production are used together, the marginal
product of any one factor depends on the quantities of all
factors that are available.
Copyright © 2014 Cengage Learning
Summary
As a result, a change in the supply of one factor alters the
equilibrium earnings of all the factors.
Workers earn different wages for many reasons.
To some extent, wage differentials compensate workers for job
attributes.
Workers with more human capital get paid more than workers
with less human capital.
The return to accumulating human capital is high and has
increased over the past decade.
There is much variation in earnings that cannot be explained by
things economists can measure.
Copyright © 2014 Cengage Learning
Summary
The unexplained variation in earnings is largely attributable to
natural ability, effort, and chance.
Signalling could partly help explain why more highly educated
workers earn higher wages.
Wages are sometimes pushed above the equilibrium level
because of minimum wage laws, unions, and efficiency wages.
Some differences in earnings are attributable to discrimination
on the basis of race, sex, or other factors.
Copyright © 2014 Cengage Learning
Summary
When measuring the amount of discrimination, one must correct
for differences in human capital and job characteristics.
Competitive markets tend to limit the impact of discrimination
on wages.
Discrimination can persist in competitive markets if customers
are
willing to pay more to discriminatory firms,
or if the government passes laws requiring firms to
discriminate.
The UK’s minimum wage – not so good after all?
(words 1998)
W S Siebert, Feb 2013
Introduction
There has been a decline in labour market prospects for the
most vulnerable groups since the minimum wage was introduced
in the UK. There is not sufficient UK evidence yet to pin much
of the blame for this on the minimum wage, but the
international evidence points in that direction. Proposals for
imposing a “living wage” by soft or hard coercion could also be
damaging.
Brief history
The UK’s minimum wage began in April 1999, fulfilling a
promise of Blair’s new Labour government. Blair was
responding to popular demand, since the Conservative
government in 1993 had ended the old system of minimum
wages. Michael Forsyth, the Employment Minister at the time
said: “The biggest source of poverty is not low pay; it is having
no job. Wages councils destroy employment”. However, most
people, then and now, believe that there is a moral basis for a
minimum wage, and the coalition government has not moved
close to changing it.
The national minimum wage (NMW) system has some
interesting features. Firstly, it is set in a technocratic way by
experts who rely on research. Although the Low Pay
Commission has both TUC and CBI members, it also has
academic members, and an independent chair. Hence, a careful
sifting of the evidence on how the NMW bears on business –
including business in the regions plays a large part in the
debate. As such, changes in the NMW have responded closely to
changes in the health of the economy. The biggest exception to
this was in 2001 when the thrusting Stephen Byers saw electoral
advantage in pushing the youth rate up considerably prior to the
May 2001 election. The important point here is that the NMW is
set explicitly to weigh as little on unemployment as possible.
Secondly, the minimum wage is “national”, with no regional
differentiation. The Low Pay Commission’s terms of reference
from the beginning excluded such differentiation. Hence,
arguably, the level has always been too high for the north, and
too low for the London area. The NMW does, however, have
several age categories, with a youth sub-minimum, and an even
lower apprentice sub-minimum. Thus, it has been sensibly
conceded that young workers and apprentices are less
productive. Again, we see an effort to mute the unemployment
consequences of the minimum.
Despite this, the UK labour market is performing poorly for
unskilled workers, as shown in Table 1, and the question must
arise about the NMW’s role in this. We see that the 16-24
group’s unemployment rate has almost doubled to 24.7 per cent
over the period since 1999. In addition, as the lower panel
shows, their unemployment duration has worsened, with 28.2
per cent unemployed for over one year. In fact, as can be seen,
the UK’s youth labour market is now putting in as bad a
performance as France, long a youth unemployment blackspot
Employment effects
UK evidence. The minimum wage has been raised considerably
over the period since 1999. Hence, it makes a lot of difference
to unskilled workers’ earnings, and one would expect
unemployment consequences unless counter-balanced by strong
growth. The impact of the minimum wage can be seen in Figure
1. The 2010 distribution has had its lower tail cut off compared
with the 1997. In fact, the NMW has increased by 72 per cent
since 1999, considerably more than the 50% of the average
worker’s wage.
What effect has this had on job opportunities for the unskilled?
There are inherent statistical difficulties of identifying the
impacts of a policy that covers the whole of the UK. One way to
judge this issue is to examine regional variation, since the
NMW has more “bite” in poor than rich areas as shown in
Figure 2, which compares the hypothetical effect in a district
such as Cambridge with one such as Liverpool. Assume that
productivity and the demand for labour is lower in Liverpool.
The NMW requirement would move unskilled employment from
point d (dictated by the level of welfare benefits) to point c (the
demand for labour at the minimum wage). Meanwhile,
employment in Cambridge would be barely affected.
The first person to conduct this type of study was Mark Stewart
(2002), who used data for changes in wages and employment in
about 150 UK regions for the first year of the NMW. He found
no adverse effect, but with only one data point per region he
could not allow for region-specific trends or long-run effects.
His work has recently been updated (Dolton et al 2013, 26)
using all data including the recession, and concludes the regions
with more NMW bite indeed have lower employment other
things equal:
The elasticity is around 0.1 implying that a 10 percent increase
in the bite of the minimum wage [relative to the area
wage]would lead to a fall of 1 per cent of the employment rate”.
An alternative approach is to compare workers who have their
wages raised by the NMW with workers paid just above that
level (say, up to 10 per cent above the minimum). These
workers should have similar skills, and welfare benefit options.
This method was also pioneered for the UK by Stewart (2004).
He again found no adverse NMW employment effects, but was
only looking at one year of data.
In fact, the latest work using this approach by Dickens and
Riley (2012), using data up to 2010, does find unskilled workers
are hit harder. In particular, this research finds that the
probability of remaining in job (employment retention) is
reduced by about three percentage points by the NMW for part-
time women, the group who are most affected by the NMW
(10% compared to about 2-3% for full-timers). This result is
important because a 3 point reduction is large when measured
against an average retention rate (i.e. probability of remaining
in employment for one year) of around 70 per cent.
So, the UK employment picture for the most vulnerable has
deteriorated with the NMW. However, there is not enough data
to draw firm conclusions as to the cause as yet. What does the
international evidence suggest?
International evidence. Studying a panel of countries or states
(for example in the USA) offers a better way of analysing
minimum wages since there is more variation in the minimum.
An important study of long-run effects is that by Baker at al
(1999) for nine Canadian provinces for 1975-93. He found that
a 10 per cent increase in the minimum wage reduces teenage
employment by 2.5 per cent and that it takes about six years for
the full result.
There have been other international panel studies, all finding
adverse effects. Neumark and Wascher’s (2004) analysis of 17
OECD countries for the period 1975-2000 finds that a 10 per
cent increase in the minimum wage leads to a two per cent
reduction in the employment rate for younger people (15-24).
Recent work by Dolton and Bondiabene (2012) confirms these
estimates and also suggests that the impact of minimum wages
tends to double during a recession.
Finally, the work by Addison and Ozturk (2012) concentrates on
employment outcomes for adult women. They estimate that a 10
per cent increase in the minimum wage will reduce employment
by 1.5 per cent.
In sum, while the UK evidence is thinner due to statistical
problems, the research overall points to the minimum wage
reducing employment as conventional economic theory predicts.
In other words, the minimum wage undermines employment for
the least productive whilst raising wages for others. The
research also suggests that the workers who benefit are the
better-off. Thus, where there is high unemployment there is
heightened competition for jobs, with the better connected
workers – teenagers from better educated families rather than
the poor finding them (see Ahn et al. 2011).
Morality and new proposals for a “living wage”
Going beyond the NMW, the Joseph Rowntree Foundation and
others are calling for a “living wage” of £7.45 an hour. We are
told that “the moral pressures are winning out over the
economic pressures” (Hirsh 2012). Yet what moral virtue is
there in a policy that causes the loss of jobs for low-wage, low-
skill workers or which causes the lengthening of unemployment
duration? Countries with high minimum wages and/or high
social costs - such as France - have high long-term
unemployment (where nearly half the unemployed have been
jobless for longer than a year).
The living wage would be tied only to living costs and median
incomes and not to labour market conditions. As we have seen,
the unemployment effect of the UK minimum wage has been
reduced because of the pragmatism of those setting the rate. The
imposition of the living wage – regardless of labour market
conditions - would be a recipe for increased long-term
unemployment.
A functioning market would have much lower wages in
Liverpool than in Cambridge, which would attract business, and
relieve poor unemployed people. If the market were allowed to
work – which would require lower benefits as well as lower
wages since benefits form a floor under wages - then businesses
would move north. Of course, it is difficult to take on the
benefit system, but even tax breaks for businesses in
development areas would be better than a living wage. The
living wage would push wages up for favoured workers in large
firms and in government, but would do nothing for those
trapped within our dysfunctional “permanent” welfare system.In
fact, there are other policies, such as better schooling (and
reduced teacher union power), reduced regulation and taxes,
that could enable unskilled workers to become independent and
earn their their own “living wages”.
References
Addison John and Orgul Ozturk (2012). “Minimum Wages,
Labor Market Institutions, and Female Employment: A Cross-
Country Analysis”, Industrial and Labor Relations Review, 65:
779-809.
Ahn, Tom, Peter Arcidiacono and Walter Wessels (2011). “The
Distributional Impacts of Minimum Wage Increases when both
Labor Supply and Labor Demand are Endogenous”, 29: 12-23.
Baker, Michael, Dwayne Benjamin and Shuchita Stanger (1999).
“The Highs and Lows of the Minimum Wage Effect: A Time-
Series Cross-Section Study of the Canadian Law”, Journal of
Labor Economics, 17: 318-50.
Commission (2012). National Minimum Wage - Report 2012,
Cm 8302, London: Low Pay Commission.
Dickens, Richard, Rebecca Riley and David Wilkinson (2012),
“Re-examining the Impact of the National Minimum Wage on
Earnings, Employment and Hours: the Importance of Recession
and Firm Size”, Research Report Commissioned for the 2012
Report, http://www.lowpay.gov.uk/lowpay/research/pdf/
Dolton, Peter and Chiara Bondibene (2012). “The International
Experience of Minimum Wages in an Economic Downturn”,
Economic Policy, 27: 99-142.
Dolton, Peter, Chiara Bondibene and Michael Stops, 2013.
“Identifying the Employment Effect of Invoking and Changing
the Minimum Wage: A Spatial Analysis of the UK”,
unpublished working paper, University of Sussex.
Hirsch, Donald (2012), “The Living Wage: Where Morality and
Economics Meet”, Joseph Rowntree Foundation,
www.jrf.org.uk/focus-issue/minimum-income-standards
Stewart, Mark (2002), “Estimating the Impact of the Minimum
Wage Using Geographic Wage Variation”, Oxford Bulletin of
Economics and Statistics, 64: 583-606.
Stewart, Mark (2004), The impact of the introduction of the UK
minimum wage on the employment probabilities of low wage
workers. Journal of the European Economic Association, 2: 67–
97.
Figure 1: Changes in the Earnings Distribution due to the NMW
Source: Commission (2011), Figure 2.9
(
Supply
D
C
ambridge
wage
a
Welfare
Labour hours
D
L
iverpool
NMW
b
c
d
)
Figure 2: Assessment of NMW Effects
Table 1: Adverse Changes in Employment for Unskilled
Workers
All, 16-65
No qualifications
16-24
France, 15-24
Unemployment rate (%)
1999
6.3
12.1
13.8
24.2
2011
8.1
17.0
24.7
22.1
Change 1999-2011 (% points)
1.8
7.9
10.9
-2.1
Unemployment duration (% of unemployed > 12 months)
1999
28.7
NA
15.3
France, total
40.3
2011
33.3
NA
28.2
41.4
Change 1999-2011 (% points)
4.6
NA
12.9
1.1
Sources: Commission (2012, Table 2.10), ONS (2012) and
OECD (2000, 2012)
6
Intermediate Business Economics and the Macroeconomy
UPDATED ESSAY NOTES
W S Siebert, 28/9/15
The essay task is to choose ONE area of economic policy from
the list below, regulated by a Singapore government authority
as shown. Explain the relevant economics that underlies the
area you choose. Summarise and evaluate the arguments for and
against intervention by the authority. (2000 words essay)
The areas are as follows, choose ONE:
1) Electricity supply and pricing – authority: Energy Market
Authority (EMA)
2) Competition and merger regulation authority: Competition
Commission of Singapore (CCS)
3) Environmental protection authority: Natural Environment
Agency (NEA)
4) Wage regulation authority: National Wages Council (NWC)
(we will be working on wage regulation for this essay, so u can
ignore the first three.)
Deadline: 4th November 2015; length: text 2000 words
(references, tables, graphs and appendices are excluded from
the count); at least one table and one graph must be included in
your essay, and at least 6 references
Basic Structure
A structure that highlights the economic issues and solutions
(and compromises) discussed in the module is required.Having
chosen your area, you might build on
· a situation that has been discussed in the lectures
· a problem you have read about in a newspaper or heard about
on the news
· a discussion you find on one of the Singapore authorities’
websites
But make sure it contains economic theory relevant to the area
you have chosen, e.g.:
Area
Economic theories
Sections in Mankiw-Taylor
Electricity
Natural monopoly, utility regulation
Chap 6 (basic competition), chap14 (economies of scale, natural
monopoly, e.g. slide 35)
Competition
Monopoly power, cartels, collusion
Chap 6 (basic competition), chap 14 (monopoly and competition
compared, e.g. slide 21), chap 16 (cartels)
Environment
Externalities, property rights, prisoner’s dilemma
Chapters 10 (e.g., slide 10) and chap 11 (public goods,
externalities)
Wages
Wage determination, minimum wages, welfare safety nets
Chap 17 (labour markets, e.g. slides 38-9), chap 18 (inequality
slides 36-7)
Introduction:
What problem are you analysing? Give the question or
hypothesis that is to be your focus. Give a brief overview of the
main issues involved. Typical questions or hypotheses in each
of the four areas are as follows:
· electricity and the EMA: the EMA has helped to ensure low
cost and dependable electricity for Singapore
· competition and the CCS: the Competition Commission
successfully promotes competition, as shown by its decision, for
example, to stop SITIC’s exclusive agreements
· the environment and the NEA: the NEA helps improve air
quality in Singapore which is difficult given cross-border haze
problems
· wages and the NWC: the NWC’s wage “guidelines” provide
better employment opportunities than a minimum wage.
Main body:
First, I suggest starting with economic analysis. Explain the
relevant economics behind the issues. Taking the four areas in
turn we have problems of natural monopoly in the case of
electricity supply and the EMA, collusion in the case of the
CCS, the tragedy of the commons in the case of Indonesia’s
fires, and labour market supply and demand and the problem of
low wages in the case of the NWC. Start with a simple
diagrammatic analysis if possible.
Then, take up the facts and statistics. Explain the reasoning for
the authority’s policies – go to the authority’s website, and
discuss why and when it was set up. Discuss its history and
achievements, and draw up a table if possible using statistics to
demonstrate its achievements. Comparison with other countries
is not necessary, but can be useful – the UK for example, has
regulation of electricity, and also has a minimum wage.
Conclusion: what have been the advantages and disadvantages
of the authorities policies? Try and use specific examples, and
relate to supply and demand analysis as taught in the module.
Final word: keep it simple. Use your chosen authority’s website
for the practical detail of what has happened in Singapore, and
use Mankiw-Taylor for the supply and demand foundation. Tell
a story about how Singapore’s government authorities help
solve basic economic problems, using graphs and data.
Requirements
· Clear structure, with Introduction; Main body; Conclusions;
References
· Introduction sets out your questions
· Main body: develop your arguments and analysis
· Conclusions – provide a brief summary and discuss
implications (if any) for business
· References need to be complete
Writing the essay
· Stick to the word limit
· You are not being judged on the elegance of your English, but
your paragraphs must have a structure:
· beginning, middle and end
· clear leading sentence, and concluding sentence to each
paragraph
· It is good to discuss matters with others in preparing the
essay, but write everything yourself
· Leave yourself time to proofread before submitting
Explaining the Economics
· In your essay, you should show that you can understand and
apply some of the economics we have covered in this module
· Explain the theory that relates to the case you choose (see
following slides)
· You may use diagrams for your explanation (e.g. contrasting
competition with monopoly, then showing possible welfare
losses)
· Use the economics to analyse different policy measures – i.e.
refer back to the theory when discussing policies
Plagiarism
· Make sure you use your own words when writing the essay
· All sources need to be correctly referenced
· Do not copy and paste: this is the best way to avoid plagiarism
· Use direct quotes only when absolutely necessary
· Beware of collusion: working closely with a friend on a
similar topic and writing very similar essays
· Your essay will be checked for plagiarism
· Consequences can be significant
Summary of Advice
· Choose an area quickly and collect information
· Remember that to get a good mark you need to show that you
can understand and apply the relevant economics
· It is a short essay:– every word must be necessary
· Make sure your essay is written in your own words all essays
are checked for copying using Turnitin
· Any questions? Ask now or email me
1

More Related Content

Similar to Forthcoming in Chris Coyne and Rachel Coyne – Floors and Ceilings.docx

Dinkelman ranchhod minwages_0710
Dinkelman ranchhod minwages_0710Dinkelman ranchhod minwages_0710
Dinkelman ranchhod minwages_0710Dr Lendy Spires
 
How do regulated and unregulated labor markets respond to shocks? Evidence fr...
How do regulated and unregulated labor markets respond to shocks? Evidence fr...How do regulated and unregulated labor markets respond to shocks? Evidence fr...
How do regulated and unregulated labor markets respond to shocks? Evidence fr...Stockholm Institute of Transition Economics
 
Menzies Law White Paper - Gender Pay Gap
Menzies Law White Paper - Gender Pay GapMenzies Law White Paper - Gender Pay Gap
Menzies Law White Paper - Gender Pay GapLuke Menzies
 
Student answer  The French and the German were a bit different w.docx
Student answer  The French and the German were a bit different w.docxStudent answer  The French and the German were a bit different w.docx
Student answer  The French and the German were a bit different w.docxjohniemcm5zt
 
Four Day Workweek Policy For Improving Employment and Environmental Condition...
Four Day Workweek Policy For Improving Employment and Environmental Condition...Four Day Workweek Policy For Improving Employment and Environmental Condition...
Four Day Workweek Policy For Improving Employment and Environmental Condition...Sociotechnical Roundtable
 
Labour Taxation and Employment: An Analysis with a Macroeconomic Model for th...
Labour Taxation and Employment: An Analysis with a Macroeconomic Model for th...Labour Taxation and Employment: An Analysis with a Macroeconomic Model for th...
Labour Taxation and Employment: An Analysis with a Macroeconomic Model for th...Palkansaajien tutkimuslaitos
 
Crisis and Welfare Society in Spain
Crisis and Welfare Society in SpainCrisis and Welfare Society in Spain
Crisis and Welfare Society in Spaininventionjournals
 
Public provision, commodity demand and hours of work: An empirical analysis
Public provision, commodity demand and hours of work: An empirical analysisPublic provision, commodity demand and hours of work: An empirical analysis
Public provision, commodity demand and hours of work: An empirical analysisPalkansaajien tutkimuslaitos
 
Tax Policy and Employment: How Does the Swedish System Fare
Tax Policy and Employment: How Does the Swedish System FareTax Policy and Employment: How Does the Swedish System Fare
Tax Policy and Employment: How Does the Swedish System FarePalkansaajien tutkimuslaitos
 
Chapter 7 macro
Chapter 7 macroChapter 7 macro
Chapter 7 macroMDevSNPT
 
MACROECONOMICS-CH6
MACROECONOMICS-CH6MACROECONOMICS-CH6
MACROECONOMICS-CH6kkjjkevin03
 
Informal Sector, Productivity and Tax Collection
 Informal Sector, Productivity and Tax Collection Informal Sector, Productivity and Tax Collection
Informal Sector, Productivity and Tax CollectionDr Lendy Spires
 

Similar to Forthcoming in Chris Coyne and Rachel Coyne – Floors and Ceilings.docx (16)

Dinkelman ranchhod minwages_0710
Dinkelman ranchhod minwages_0710Dinkelman ranchhod minwages_0710
Dinkelman ranchhod minwages_0710
 
How do regulated and unregulated labor markets respond to shocks? Evidence fr...
How do regulated and unregulated labor markets respond to shocks? Evidence fr...How do regulated and unregulated labor markets respond to shocks? Evidence fr...
How do regulated and unregulated labor markets respond to shocks? Evidence fr...
 
Menzies Law White Paper - Gender Pay Gap
Menzies Law White Paper - Gender Pay GapMenzies Law White Paper - Gender Pay Gap
Menzies Law White Paper - Gender Pay Gap
 
Student answer  The French and the German were a bit different w.docx
Student answer  The French and the German were a bit different w.docxStudent answer  The French and the German were a bit different w.docx
Student answer  The French and the German were a bit different w.docx
 
Whose welfare state now
Whose welfare state nowWhose welfare state now
Whose welfare state now
 
Four Day Workweek Policy For Improving Employment and Environmental Condition...
Four Day Workweek Policy For Improving Employment and Environmental Condition...Four Day Workweek Policy For Improving Employment and Environmental Condition...
Four Day Workweek Policy For Improving Employment and Environmental Condition...
 
Research Paper
Research PaperResearch Paper
Research Paper
 
Labour Taxation and Employment: An Analysis with a Macroeconomic Model for th...
Labour Taxation and Employment: An Analysis with a Macroeconomic Model for th...Labour Taxation and Employment: An Analysis with a Macroeconomic Model for th...
Labour Taxation and Employment: An Analysis with a Macroeconomic Model for th...
 
Crisis and Welfare Society in Spain
Crisis and Welfare Society in SpainCrisis and Welfare Society in Spain
Crisis and Welfare Society in Spain
 
Public provision, commodity demand and hours of work: An empirical analysis
Public provision, commodity demand and hours of work: An empirical analysisPublic provision, commodity demand and hours of work: An empirical analysis
Public provision, commodity demand and hours of work: An empirical analysis
 
What we pay in the shadow: Labor tax evasion, minimum wage hike and employment
What we pay in the shadow: Labor tax evasion, minimum wage hike and employmentWhat we pay in the shadow: Labor tax evasion, minimum wage hike and employment
What we pay in the shadow: Labor tax evasion, minimum wage hike and employment
 
Tax Policy and Employment: How Does the Swedish System Fare
Tax Policy and Employment: How Does the Swedish System FareTax Policy and Employment: How Does the Swedish System Fare
Tax Policy and Employment: How Does the Swedish System Fare
 
Chapter 7 macro
Chapter 7 macroChapter 7 macro
Chapter 7 macro
 
MACROECONOMICS-CH6
MACROECONOMICS-CH6MACROECONOMICS-CH6
MACROECONOMICS-CH6
 
Implications of a Basic Income - Maureen O'Reilly
Implications of a Basic Income - Maureen O'ReillyImplications of a Basic Income - Maureen O'Reilly
Implications of a Basic Income - Maureen O'Reilly
 
Informal Sector, Productivity and Tax Collection
 Informal Sector, Productivity and Tax Collection Informal Sector, Productivity and Tax Collection
Informal Sector, Productivity and Tax Collection
 

More from hanneloremccaffery

 Explain how firms can benefit from forecastingexchange rates .docx
 Explain how firms can benefit from forecastingexchange rates .docx Explain how firms can benefit from forecastingexchange rates .docx
 Explain how firms can benefit from forecastingexchange rates .docxhanneloremccaffery
 
•POL201 •Discussions •Week 5 - DiscussionVoter and Voter Tu.docx
•POL201 •Discussions •Week 5 - DiscussionVoter and Voter Tu.docx•POL201 •Discussions •Week 5 - DiscussionVoter and Voter Tu.docx
•POL201 •Discussions •Week 5 - DiscussionVoter and Voter Tu.docxhanneloremccaffery
 
•No less than 4 pages causal argument researched essay •In.docx
•No less than 4 pages causal argument researched essay •In.docx•No less than 4 pages causal argument researched essay •In.docx
•No less than 4 pages causal argument researched essay •In.docxhanneloremccaffery
 
•Focus on two or three things in the Mesopotamian andor Ovids ac.docx
•Focus on two or three things in the Mesopotamian andor Ovids ac.docx•Focus on two or three things in the Mesopotamian andor Ovids ac.docx
•Focus on two or three things in the Mesopotamian andor Ovids ac.docxhanneloremccaffery
 
•Langbein, L. (2012). Public program evaluation A statistical guide.docx
•Langbein, L. (2012). Public program evaluation A statistical guide.docx•Langbein, L. (2012). Public program evaluation A statistical guide.docx
•Langbein, L. (2012). Public program evaluation A statistical guide.docxhanneloremccaffery
 
•Chapter 10 Do you think it is possible for an outsider to accura.docx
•Chapter 10 Do you think it is possible for an outsider to accura.docx•Chapter 10 Do you think it is possible for an outsider to accura.docx
•Chapter 10 Do you think it is possible for an outsider to accura.docxhanneloremccaffery
 
·         Bakit Di gaanong kaganda ang pagturo sa UST sa panahon.docx
·         Bakit Di gaanong kaganda ang pagturo sa UST sa panahon.docx·         Bakit Di gaanong kaganda ang pagturo sa UST sa panahon.docx
·         Bakit Di gaanong kaganda ang pagturo sa UST sa panahon.docxhanneloremccaffery
 
·YOUR INDIVIDUAL PAPER IS ARGUMENTATIVE OR POSITIONAL(Heal.docx
·YOUR INDIVIDUAL PAPER IS ARGUMENTATIVE OR POSITIONAL(Heal.docx·YOUR INDIVIDUAL PAPER IS ARGUMENTATIVE OR POSITIONAL(Heal.docx
·YOUR INDIVIDUAL PAPER IS ARGUMENTATIVE OR POSITIONAL(Heal.docxhanneloremccaffery
 
·Write a 750- to 1,Write a 750- to 1,200-word paper that.docx
·Write a 750- to 1,Write a 750- to 1,200-word paper that.docx·Write a 750- to 1,Write a 750- to 1,200-word paper that.docx
·Write a 750- to 1,Write a 750- to 1,200-word paper that.docxhanneloremccaffery
 
[Type here]Ok. This school makes me confused. The summary of t.docx
[Type here]Ok. This school makes me confused. The summary of t.docx[Type here]Ok. This school makes me confused. The summary of t.docx
[Type here]Ok. This school makes me confused. The summary of t.docxhanneloremccaffery
 
© 2020 Cengage Learning®. May not be scanned, copied or duplic.docx
© 2020 Cengage Learning®. May not be scanned, copied or duplic.docx© 2020 Cengage Learning®. May not be scanned, copied or duplic.docx
© 2020 Cengage Learning®. May not be scanned, copied or duplic.docxhanneloremccaffery
 
© 2016 Laureate Education, Inc. Page 1 of 3 RWRCOEL Prof.docx
© 2016 Laureate Education, Inc.   Page 1 of 3 RWRCOEL Prof.docx© 2016 Laureate Education, Inc.   Page 1 of 3 RWRCOEL Prof.docx
© 2016 Laureate Education, Inc. Page 1 of 3 RWRCOEL Prof.docxhanneloremccaffery
 
© 2022 Post University, ALL RIGHTS RESERVED Due Date.docx
© 2022 Post University, ALL RIGHTS RESERVED  Due Date.docx© 2022 Post University, ALL RIGHTS RESERVED  Due Date.docx
© 2022 Post University, ALL RIGHTS RESERVED Due Date.docxhanneloremccaffery
 
{DiscriminationGENERAL DISCRIMINATI.docx
{DiscriminationGENERAL DISCRIMINATI.docx{DiscriminationGENERAL DISCRIMINATI.docx
{DiscriminationGENERAL DISCRIMINATI.docxhanneloremccaffery
 
~UEER THEORY AND THE JEWISH QUESTI01 Daniel Boyarin, Da.docx
~UEER THEORY AND THE JEWISH QUESTI01 Daniel Boyarin, Da.docx~UEER THEORY AND THE JEWISH QUESTI01 Daniel Boyarin, Da.docx
~UEER THEORY AND THE JEWISH QUESTI01 Daniel Boyarin, Da.docxhanneloremccaffery
 
© 2017 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved.Chapter Twelve.docx
©  2017 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved.Chapter Twelve.docx©  2017 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved.Chapter Twelve.docx
© 2017 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved.Chapter Twelve.docxhanneloremccaffery
 
`HISTORY 252AEarly Modern Europe from 1500 to 1815Dr. Burton .docx
`HISTORY 252AEarly Modern Europe from 1500 to 1815Dr. Burton .docx`HISTORY 252AEarly Modern Europe from 1500 to 1815Dr. Burton .docx
`HISTORY 252AEarly Modern Europe from 1500 to 1815Dr. Burton .docxhanneloremccaffery
 
^ Acadumy of Management Journal2001. Vol. 44. No. 2. 219-237.docx
^ Acadumy of Management Journal2001. Vol. 44. No. 2. 219-237.docx^ Acadumy of Management Journal2001. Vol. 44. No. 2. 219-237.docx
^ Acadumy of Management Journal2001. Vol. 44. No. 2. 219-237.docxhanneloremccaffery
 
__MACOSXSujan Poster._CNA320 Poster Presentation rubric.pdf.docx
__MACOSXSujan Poster._CNA320 Poster Presentation rubric.pdf.docx__MACOSXSujan Poster._CNA320 Poster Presentation rubric.pdf.docx
__MACOSXSujan Poster._CNA320 Poster Presentation rubric.pdf.docxhanneloremccaffery
 

More from hanneloremccaffery (20)

 Explain how firms can benefit from forecastingexchange rates .docx
 Explain how firms can benefit from forecastingexchange rates .docx Explain how firms can benefit from forecastingexchange rates .docx
 Explain how firms can benefit from forecastingexchange rates .docx
 
•POL201 •Discussions •Week 5 - DiscussionVoter and Voter Tu.docx
•POL201 •Discussions •Week 5 - DiscussionVoter and Voter Tu.docx•POL201 •Discussions •Week 5 - DiscussionVoter and Voter Tu.docx
•POL201 •Discussions •Week 5 - DiscussionVoter and Voter Tu.docx
 
•No less than 4 pages causal argument researched essay •In.docx
•No less than 4 pages causal argument researched essay •In.docx•No less than 4 pages causal argument researched essay •In.docx
•No less than 4 pages causal argument researched essay •In.docx
 
•Focus on two or three things in the Mesopotamian andor Ovids ac.docx
•Focus on two or three things in the Mesopotamian andor Ovids ac.docx•Focus on two or three things in the Mesopotamian andor Ovids ac.docx
•Focus on two or three things in the Mesopotamian andor Ovids ac.docx
 
•Langbein, L. (2012). Public program evaluation A statistical guide.docx
•Langbein, L. (2012). Public program evaluation A statistical guide.docx•Langbein, L. (2012). Public program evaluation A statistical guide.docx
•Langbein, L. (2012). Public program evaluation A statistical guide.docx
 
•Chapter 10 Do you think it is possible for an outsider to accura.docx
•Chapter 10 Do you think it is possible for an outsider to accura.docx•Chapter 10 Do you think it is possible for an outsider to accura.docx
•Chapter 10 Do you think it is possible for an outsider to accura.docx
 
·         Bakit Di gaanong kaganda ang pagturo sa UST sa panahon.docx
·         Bakit Di gaanong kaganda ang pagturo sa UST sa panahon.docx·         Bakit Di gaanong kaganda ang pagturo sa UST sa panahon.docx
·         Bakit Di gaanong kaganda ang pagturo sa UST sa panahon.docx
 
·YOUR INDIVIDUAL PAPER IS ARGUMENTATIVE OR POSITIONAL(Heal.docx
·YOUR INDIVIDUAL PAPER IS ARGUMENTATIVE OR POSITIONAL(Heal.docx·YOUR INDIVIDUAL PAPER IS ARGUMENTATIVE OR POSITIONAL(Heal.docx
·YOUR INDIVIDUAL PAPER IS ARGUMENTATIVE OR POSITIONAL(Heal.docx
 
·Write a 750- to 1,Write a 750- to 1,200-word paper that.docx
·Write a 750- to 1,Write a 750- to 1,200-word paper that.docx·Write a 750- to 1,Write a 750- to 1,200-word paper that.docx
·Write a 750- to 1,Write a 750- to 1,200-word paper that.docx
 
[Type here]Ok. This school makes me confused. The summary of t.docx
[Type here]Ok. This school makes me confused. The summary of t.docx[Type here]Ok. This school makes me confused. The summary of t.docx
[Type here]Ok. This school makes me confused. The summary of t.docx
 
© 2020 Cengage Learning®. May not be scanned, copied or duplic.docx
© 2020 Cengage Learning®. May not be scanned, copied or duplic.docx© 2020 Cengage Learning®. May not be scanned, copied or duplic.docx
© 2020 Cengage Learning®. May not be scanned, copied or duplic.docx
 
© 2016 Laureate Education, Inc. Page 1 of 3 RWRCOEL Prof.docx
© 2016 Laureate Education, Inc.   Page 1 of 3 RWRCOEL Prof.docx© 2016 Laureate Education, Inc.   Page 1 of 3 RWRCOEL Prof.docx
© 2016 Laureate Education, Inc. Page 1 of 3 RWRCOEL Prof.docx
 
© 2022 Post University, ALL RIGHTS RESERVED Due Date.docx
© 2022 Post University, ALL RIGHTS RESERVED  Due Date.docx© 2022 Post University, ALL RIGHTS RESERVED  Due Date.docx
© 2022 Post University, ALL RIGHTS RESERVED Due Date.docx
 
{DiscriminationGENERAL DISCRIMINATI.docx
{DiscriminationGENERAL DISCRIMINATI.docx{DiscriminationGENERAL DISCRIMINATI.docx
{DiscriminationGENERAL DISCRIMINATI.docx
 
~UEER THEORY AND THE JEWISH QUESTI01 Daniel Boyarin, Da.docx
~UEER THEORY AND THE JEWISH QUESTI01 Daniel Boyarin, Da.docx~UEER THEORY AND THE JEWISH QUESTI01 Daniel Boyarin, Da.docx
~UEER THEORY AND THE JEWISH QUESTI01 Daniel Boyarin, Da.docx
 
© 2017 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved.Chapter Twelve.docx
©  2017 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved.Chapter Twelve.docx©  2017 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved.Chapter Twelve.docx
© 2017 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved.Chapter Twelve.docx
 
`HISTORY 252AEarly Modern Europe from 1500 to 1815Dr. Burton .docx
`HISTORY 252AEarly Modern Europe from 1500 to 1815Dr. Burton .docx`HISTORY 252AEarly Modern Europe from 1500 to 1815Dr. Burton .docx
`HISTORY 252AEarly Modern Europe from 1500 to 1815Dr. Burton .docx
 
^ Acadumy of Management Journal2001. Vol. 44. No. 2. 219-237.docx
^ Acadumy of Management Journal2001. Vol. 44. No. 2. 219-237.docx^ Acadumy of Management Journal2001. Vol. 44. No. 2. 219-237.docx
^ Acadumy of Management Journal2001. Vol. 44. No. 2. 219-237.docx
 
`Inclusiveness. The main.docx
`Inclusiveness. The main.docx`Inclusiveness. The main.docx
`Inclusiveness. The main.docx
 
__MACOSXSujan Poster._CNA320 Poster Presentation rubric.pdf.docx
__MACOSXSujan Poster._CNA320 Poster Presentation rubric.pdf.docx__MACOSXSujan Poster._CNA320 Poster Presentation rubric.pdf.docx
__MACOSXSujan Poster._CNA320 Poster Presentation rubric.pdf.docx
 

Recently uploaded

“Oh GOSH! Reflecting on Hackteria's Collaborative Practices in a Global Do-It...
“Oh GOSH! Reflecting on Hackteria's Collaborative Practices in a Global Do-It...“Oh GOSH! Reflecting on Hackteria's Collaborative Practices in a Global Do-It...
“Oh GOSH! Reflecting on Hackteria's Collaborative Practices in a Global Do-It...Marc Dusseiller Dusjagr
 
A Critique of the Proposed National Education Policy Reform
A Critique of the Proposed National Education Policy ReformA Critique of the Proposed National Education Policy Reform
A Critique of the Proposed National Education Policy ReformChameera Dedduwage
 
Presiding Officer Training module 2024 lok sabha elections
Presiding Officer Training module 2024 lok sabha electionsPresiding Officer Training module 2024 lok sabha elections
Presiding Officer Training module 2024 lok sabha electionsanshu789521
 
Employee wellbeing at the workplace.pptx
Employee wellbeing at the workplace.pptxEmployee wellbeing at the workplace.pptx
Employee wellbeing at the workplace.pptxNirmalaLoungPoorunde1
 
Kisan Call Centre - To harness potential of ICT in Agriculture by answer farm...
Kisan Call Centre - To harness potential of ICT in Agriculture by answer farm...Kisan Call Centre - To harness potential of ICT in Agriculture by answer farm...
Kisan Call Centre - To harness potential of ICT in Agriculture by answer farm...Krashi Coaching
 
Introduction to ArtificiaI Intelligence in Higher Education
Introduction to ArtificiaI Intelligence in Higher EducationIntroduction to ArtificiaI Intelligence in Higher Education
Introduction to ArtificiaI Intelligence in Higher Educationpboyjonauth
 
Organic Name Reactions for the students and aspirants of Chemistry12th.pptx
Organic Name Reactions  for the students and aspirants of Chemistry12th.pptxOrganic Name Reactions  for the students and aspirants of Chemistry12th.pptx
Organic Name Reactions for the students and aspirants of Chemistry12th.pptxVS Mahajan Coaching Centre
 
Contemporary philippine arts from the regions_PPT_Module_12 [Autosaved] (1).pptx
Contemporary philippine arts from the regions_PPT_Module_12 [Autosaved] (1).pptxContemporary philippine arts from the regions_PPT_Module_12 [Autosaved] (1).pptx
Contemporary philippine arts from the regions_PPT_Module_12 [Autosaved] (1).pptxRoyAbrique
 
Alper Gobel In Media Res Media Component
Alper Gobel In Media Res Media ComponentAlper Gobel In Media Res Media Component
Alper Gobel In Media Res Media ComponentInMediaRes1
 
Solving Puzzles Benefits Everyone (English).pptx
Solving Puzzles Benefits Everyone (English).pptxSolving Puzzles Benefits Everyone (English).pptx
Solving Puzzles Benefits Everyone (English).pptxOH TEIK BIN
 
ECONOMIC CONTEXT - LONG FORM TV DRAMA - PPT
ECONOMIC CONTEXT - LONG FORM TV DRAMA - PPTECONOMIC CONTEXT - LONG FORM TV DRAMA - PPT
ECONOMIC CONTEXT - LONG FORM TV DRAMA - PPTiammrhaywood
 
mini mental status format.docx
mini    mental       status     format.docxmini    mental       status     format.docx
mini mental status format.docxPoojaSen20
 
Introduction to AI in Higher Education_draft.pptx
Introduction to AI in Higher Education_draft.pptxIntroduction to AI in Higher Education_draft.pptx
Introduction to AI in Higher Education_draft.pptxpboyjonauth
 
18-04-UA_REPORT_MEDIALITERAСY_INDEX-DM_23-1-final-eng.pdf
18-04-UA_REPORT_MEDIALITERAСY_INDEX-DM_23-1-final-eng.pdf18-04-UA_REPORT_MEDIALITERAСY_INDEX-DM_23-1-final-eng.pdf
18-04-UA_REPORT_MEDIALITERAСY_INDEX-DM_23-1-final-eng.pdfssuser54595a
 
Class 11 Legal Studies Ch-1 Concept of State .pdf
Class 11 Legal Studies Ch-1 Concept of State .pdfClass 11 Legal Studies Ch-1 Concept of State .pdf
Class 11 Legal Studies Ch-1 Concept of State .pdfakmcokerachita
 
POINT- BIOCHEMISTRY SEM 2 ENZYMES UNIT 5.pptx
POINT- BIOCHEMISTRY SEM 2 ENZYMES UNIT 5.pptxPOINT- BIOCHEMISTRY SEM 2 ENZYMES UNIT 5.pptx
POINT- BIOCHEMISTRY SEM 2 ENZYMES UNIT 5.pptxSayali Powar
 
call girls in Kamla Market (DELHI) 🔝 >༒9953330565🔝 genuine Escort Service 🔝✔️✔️
call girls in Kamla Market (DELHI) 🔝 >༒9953330565🔝 genuine Escort Service 🔝✔️✔️call girls in Kamla Market (DELHI) 🔝 >༒9953330565🔝 genuine Escort Service 🔝✔️✔️
call girls in Kamla Market (DELHI) 🔝 >༒9953330565🔝 genuine Escort Service 🔝✔️✔️9953056974 Low Rate Call Girls In Saket, Delhi NCR
 
Interactive Powerpoint_How to Master effective communication
Interactive Powerpoint_How to Master effective communicationInteractive Powerpoint_How to Master effective communication
Interactive Powerpoint_How to Master effective communicationnomboosow
 

Recently uploaded (20)

“Oh GOSH! Reflecting on Hackteria's Collaborative Practices in a Global Do-It...
“Oh GOSH! Reflecting on Hackteria's Collaborative Practices in a Global Do-It...“Oh GOSH! Reflecting on Hackteria's Collaborative Practices in a Global Do-It...
“Oh GOSH! Reflecting on Hackteria's Collaborative Practices in a Global Do-It...
 
A Critique of the Proposed National Education Policy Reform
A Critique of the Proposed National Education Policy ReformA Critique of the Proposed National Education Policy Reform
A Critique of the Proposed National Education Policy Reform
 
Presiding Officer Training module 2024 lok sabha elections
Presiding Officer Training module 2024 lok sabha electionsPresiding Officer Training module 2024 lok sabha elections
Presiding Officer Training module 2024 lok sabha elections
 
Employee wellbeing at the workplace.pptx
Employee wellbeing at the workplace.pptxEmployee wellbeing at the workplace.pptx
Employee wellbeing at the workplace.pptx
 
Kisan Call Centre - To harness potential of ICT in Agriculture by answer farm...
Kisan Call Centre - To harness potential of ICT in Agriculture by answer farm...Kisan Call Centre - To harness potential of ICT in Agriculture by answer farm...
Kisan Call Centre - To harness potential of ICT in Agriculture by answer farm...
 
Introduction to ArtificiaI Intelligence in Higher Education
Introduction to ArtificiaI Intelligence in Higher EducationIntroduction to ArtificiaI Intelligence in Higher Education
Introduction to ArtificiaI Intelligence in Higher Education
 
9953330565 Low Rate Call Girls In Rohini Delhi NCR
9953330565 Low Rate Call Girls In Rohini  Delhi NCR9953330565 Low Rate Call Girls In Rohini  Delhi NCR
9953330565 Low Rate Call Girls In Rohini Delhi NCR
 
Organic Name Reactions for the students and aspirants of Chemistry12th.pptx
Organic Name Reactions  for the students and aspirants of Chemistry12th.pptxOrganic Name Reactions  for the students and aspirants of Chemistry12th.pptx
Organic Name Reactions for the students and aspirants of Chemistry12th.pptx
 
Contemporary philippine arts from the regions_PPT_Module_12 [Autosaved] (1).pptx
Contemporary philippine arts from the regions_PPT_Module_12 [Autosaved] (1).pptxContemporary philippine arts from the regions_PPT_Module_12 [Autosaved] (1).pptx
Contemporary philippine arts from the regions_PPT_Module_12 [Autosaved] (1).pptx
 
Alper Gobel In Media Res Media Component
Alper Gobel In Media Res Media ComponentAlper Gobel In Media Res Media Component
Alper Gobel In Media Res Media Component
 
Solving Puzzles Benefits Everyone (English).pptx
Solving Puzzles Benefits Everyone (English).pptxSolving Puzzles Benefits Everyone (English).pptx
Solving Puzzles Benefits Everyone (English).pptx
 
ECONOMIC CONTEXT - LONG FORM TV DRAMA - PPT
ECONOMIC CONTEXT - LONG FORM TV DRAMA - PPTECONOMIC CONTEXT - LONG FORM TV DRAMA - PPT
ECONOMIC CONTEXT - LONG FORM TV DRAMA - PPT
 
Staff of Color (SOC) Retention Efforts DDSD
Staff of Color (SOC) Retention Efforts DDSDStaff of Color (SOC) Retention Efforts DDSD
Staff of Color (SOC) Retention Efforts DDSD
 
mini mental status format.docx
mini    mental       status     format.docxmini    mental       status     format.docx
mini mental status format.docx
 
Introduction to AI in Higher Education_draft.pptx
Introduction to AI in Higher Education_draft.pptxIntroduction to AI in Higher Education_draft.pptx
Introduction to AI in Higher Education_draft.pptx
 
18-04-UA_REPORT_MEDIALITERAСY_INDEX-DM_23-1-final-eng.pdf
18-04-UA_REPORT_MEDIALITERAСY_INDEX-DM_23-1-final-eng.pdf18-04-UA_REPORT_MEDIALITERAСY_INDEX-DM_23-1-final-eng.pdf
18-04-UA_REPORT_MEDIALITERAСY_INDEX-DM_23-1-final-eng.pdf
 
Class 11 Legal Studies Ch-1 Concept of State .pdf
Class 11 Legal Studies Ch-1 Concept of State .pdfClass 11 Legal Studies Ch-1 Concept of State .pdf
Class 11 Legal Studies Ch-1 Concept of State .pdf
 
POINT- BIOCHEMISTRY SEM 2 ENZYMES UNIT 5.pptx
POINT- BIOCHEMISTRY SEM 2 ENZYMES UNIT 5.pptxPOINT- BIOCHEMISTRY SEM 2 ENZYMES UNIT 5.pptx
POINT- BIOCHEMISTRY SEM 2 ENZYMES UNIT 5.pptx
 
call girls in Kamla Market (DELHI) 🔝 >༒9953330565🔝 genuine Escort Service 🔝✔️✔️
call girls in Kamla Market (DELHI) 🔝 >༒9953330565🔝 genuine Escort Service 🔝✔️✔️call girls in Kamla Market (DELHI) 🔝 >༒9953330565🔝 genuine Escort Service 🔝✔️✔️
call girls in Kamla Market (DELHI) 🔝 >༒9953330565🔝 genuine Escort Service 🔝✔️✔️
 
Interactive Powerpoint_How to Master effective communication
Interactive Powerpoint_How to Master effective communicationInteractive Powerpoint_How to Master effective communication
Interactive Powerpoint_How to Master effective communication
 

Forthcoming in Chris Coyne and Rachel Coyne – Floors and Ceilings.docx

  • 1. Forthcoming in Chris Coyne and Rachel Coyne – “Floors and Ceilings - the economics of price controls”, London: IEA Hobart Paperback. The Simple Economics of Wage Floors W S Siebert January 2015 Birmingham University ABSTRACT The paper surveys minimum wages setting and finds adverse employment effects broadly in line with conventional economic models. UK studies generally report small effects, but the UK is poorly suited for measurement given confounding changes in welfare benefits and no regional variation. Clarity is found in better empirical settings such as Canada, with good minimum wage variations and provincial differences, and in the OECD country panels. Case studies are also reviewed including South Africa (minimum wages as a white supremacy weapon), Portugal (extended collective agreements being analogous to minimum wages, and reducing employment), and Greece (the minimum encouraging temporary work). Alternative ways of helping the poor via encouragement of stable families, more competitive school systems, and subsidies for low paid work are advanced. “My daughter’s ambition is to get a job in an office. She has Down’s syndrome. She thinks that, if she works hard, someone, somewhere will give her a job. At £6.50 per hour, it’s never going to happen. But at £2 per hour? Maybe.” (Letter to Daily Telegraph 17/1/0/14, from Candice Baxter) “There is now no sizeable lobby in the UK campaigning for the abolition of the minimum wage….In a poll of experts by the Institute for Government the minimum wage was voted the most
  • 2. successful UK government policy of the past 30 years, ahead of the Northern Ireland peace process” (Manning 2013, 65) Introduction A wage floor such as the minimum wage makes payment of low wages illegal. Such a floor clearly tends to reduce unskilled job opportunities, yet it is only one example of floors under working conditions placed by regulation. Other floors on terms and conditions of employment relate to requirements for protection against unfair dismissal, or against discrimination, or for the provision of pensions via“autoenrolment”. Moreover, we must remember that high welfare benefits also place a type of floor under wages, since for many it is not worth working for a wage lower than the welfare payments they can receive. The adverse effects of these floors can compound each other, particularly in a high tax environment, as we will show. High floors can also be imposed by union power, especially via extended collective agreements as in France. The minimum wage from the beginning has been justified by the Low Pay Commission (e.g. LPC 2000, para 3.18) as a means of achieving “equity in the workplace”. But, in most private sector businesses, equity is already achieved, in the sense that wages approximate the revenue product of the marginal worker. Private sector competition drives this result though the public sector of course does not fit this model so easily. If low wages are made illegal, then what happens is that the least productive workers cannot be employed. This result is demonstrated most clearly in the case of disabled workers, as shown in our opening quotation above. As Candice Baxter points out in her letter, her daughter could gain employment at £2 per hour, but certainly not at £6.50. One’s heart goes out to her. The celebrations of the politicians in the Institute for Government, shown in our second quotation from Professor Manning, are premature. Wage floors and other regulations of working conditions grow
  • 3. together with centralised government, and are a part of the EU dirigiste tradition. The 1989 EU Charter on Fundamental Social Rights of Workers Rights marks a watershed (see Addison and Siebert, 1994), and has subsequently become the Social Chapter of the 1992 Treaty of Maastricht and 1997 Treaty of Amsterdam. The Social Chapter sets floors to most aspects of employment conditions, including “fair remuneration”, working hours, freedom of association/unionisation, training, equal treatment for men and women (and others), compulsory worker consultative councils, and health and safety. In EU terms (Commission 2006, p5), “the purpose of labour law is to offset the inherent economic and social inequality within the employment relationship”. In other words, decent wages and conditions are due to the efforts of politicians. Thus, the role of free markets and freedom of movement in defending the under- privileged is misunderstood. Setting minimum wages is easy, but deals with the symptoms of low pay, not the causes. The political payoff from minimum wage laws is immediate. The dispersion of wages is reduced, and, since more women are low paid, so is the difference between male and female average pay (another misleading statistic). Yet nothing is done about the real problems in the labour market and the education system (see Kristian Niemietz 2012). The low level of skills acquired by children from our many single parent families is ignored, as is the worklessness among these families (see below)[footnoteRef:1]. As for really disadvantaged groups such as the disabled, the minimum wage may do much harm. Opportunities may also be reduced for students who are prevented from taking low paid internships (and may have to volunteer instead), and for those whose main work is in the home, but who would like to obtain some work to supplement household income or gain the benefits of socialising at work. The best that can be said of the minimum wage policy is that it is irrelevant to real problems of inequality and worklessness. More likely, it is part of a package combined with
  • 4. other floors on working conditions, strong unions and high taxes which make matters worse – as exemplified by Greece. [1: 26% of dependent children aged 0-18 live in single-parent families in the UK, which is almost twice as high as in France and Germany. The proportion of children being brought up in jobless families is consequently also high, around 20% (see OECD 2011a Tables 1.1 and LMF1.1A) which reduces these children’s education and employment prospects.] Our plan is next to consider research into the UK’s national minimum wage, which is difficult given the lack of regional variation and the confounding effects of high levels of welfare payments. Then, we will take up results from Canada and the US where provincial variation in the minimum gives a more suitable design for minimum wage evaluation. We will also discuss the interesting case of South Africa where minimum wages were for a time used as a weapon in the struggle for white supremacy. Here we will also discuss results from long OECD country panels, which arguably give the best design for minimum wage evaluation. Finally we will extend the discussion to consider effects of minimum wages set by collective agreement. Such minima are more detailed and intrusive as shown by Martins’ (2014) study of the “30,000 minimum wages” set by collective agreements in Portugal. UK Evidence on Employment Effects The UK is the worst place conceivable to test for minimum wage employment effects. Changes in the minimum have been quite small, they are country-wide (so there is no clear counterfactual), and they are carefully tailored to the unemployment situation so as not to exacerabate unemployment unduly. (The economists on the Low Pay Commission are apolitical, and well aware of negative employment effects). Compounding the problem is the changing welfare system which also affects employment. We should remember that in 1999, at
  • 5. the same time as the minimum wage was implemented, the government introduced Working Family Tax Credits designed to encourage work which would obviously tend to counteract minimum wage effects in the opposite direction. However, the UK research does need to be considered, if only to show that we need to be careful before concluding (see for example Leonard et al 2014) from small measured UK minimum wage effects that conventional labour market models do not work. The confounding effect of movements in welfare entitlements is shown in Figure 1. Here simple demand (D) and supply (S) curves are drawn for the unskilled labour market. If a minimum wage is imposed, equilibrium moves from point E to point A. However, if welfare benefits are brought in, or raised above the minimum, then employment falls further, to point B. If welfare benefits are pre-existing, then the impact of the minimum wage on employment will be muted. The diagram is a simplification, because apprentices and trainees will continue working for less than welfare benefits, as we discuss later. Also, welfare benefits – certainly in the UK – may vary with income from employment, so that some people receive some benefits even if they are earning a wage below the welfare floor. But the tendency remains – there is an interaction between the welfare system and the minimum wage.. Moreover, if welfare benefits are reduced, or reformed via tax credits conditional on work, employment will increase, confusing minimum wage effects. Table 1 shows welfare trends, including the important housing assistance component. Unfortunately this series on net replacement rates is not available prior to 2001, however we can analyse most of the period since the introduction of the minimum wage. As can be seen, replacement rates have declined in France and Germany (the Hartz reforms), increased for single people in the US, and increased for families but not for single people in the UK. In fact, the UK’s family replacement rates are now amongst the most generous in the OECD (Niemietz 2012,
  • 6. p46). However, some of the welfare is contingent on working at least 16 hours, and so encourages some work. In fact, Gregg et al (2012, p22) estimate that employment of single women rose by 4% when tax credits were introduced: this worked against minimum wage effects oon employment. Figure 2 demonstrates two important points about the progress of wages after the minimum was introduced. First, we see that a substantial number of people were freely working for low wages in 1998 prior to the implementation of the minimum. About 6% of the workforce is in that lower tail which grades slowly down to zero, reflecting the alternatives and productivity levels of the individuals concerned. Here Mrs Baxter’s daughter would have found her job. Secondly, we see that even after the minimum was introduced, many wish to be paid below it. Low pay is a continuing phenomenon, with currently about 200,000 adults (21 and over, i.e. 1% of the adult workforce) paid below the minimum (LPC 2014, p133). In fact, the real total is probably double this figure (Kay 2007, p35) when we add the large number of under 21s. Much of this non-compliance occurs with apprentices, who are quite happy to receive low wages while training, as do students in general. In fact, about 70% of 18-20 year old hairdressing apprentices (LPC 2014, p134) currently refuse to accept the minimum wage, for which of course the Low Pay Commission and trade unions wrongly blame the employer. A further group are the interns and volunteers, who do not enter wage distributions like Figure 1 at all, but whom the Commission sees as unfairly avoiding its system. The important point is that many people see it worthwhile to work for low or no wages. This is particularly true for students and others training in order to raise their future wages.[footnoteRef:2] [2: See Gorry [2013, p72) for a good paper on how the minimum wage obstructs training: “Inexperienced workers are unable to pay for their training through reductions in their wages. To gain experience,
  • 7. they must maintain employment in a segment of the labor market characterized by high job separation rates” – their probability of unemployment consequently rises.] A good study of adverse employment effects is provided by Dickens et al (2012), who focus on part-time women where coverage by the minimum is about 10%, twice as high as for full-timers (LPC 2014, Fig 2.1). They establish a counterfactual by comparing part-timers whose wages are raised by the minimum to those paid just above that level, i.e. 10% above. This comparison group will have similar skills and welfare benefit options. They find that the introduction of the minimum in 1999 caused the year-on-year probability of part-time women retaining a job to fall from around 0.70 to 0.65. Another way of putting this finding is that before the minimum wage, median job duration was about 1.9 years for part-time women earning around the minimum, falling to 1.7 years after the minimum, that is, a fall of around 10%. They do not find effects caused by the up-ratings as they have been too small to have much effect. For example, the recent up-rating from £6.31 to £6.50 gives a maximum uplift of 1.5% to about 5% of the workforce. As well as being small relative to welfare benefit changes, minimum wage increases have been lower in times of recession. Overall, this means that it is difficult to detect effects of changes in the minimum wage, but this result does not mean that higher increases in the future will be harmless. While minimum wage increases so far have been small, a further piece of research by Rebecca Riley (2013) brings out the negative effects of the altogether larger change that the introduction of a minimum wage equal to the “living wage” would have (see also Siebert 2014). Currently the “living wage” is calculated to be £7.65 outside London, and £8.80 in London (Living Wage “Commission”, 2014). Such a change would mean wage increases for about 25% of the workforce rather than 5%,
  • 8. and raise labour costs of young unskilled (non-university) workers by as much as 14% in sectors such as hotels and catering, and retailing. Riley shows not only that the demand elasticity for labour is negative, but also that cross-price elasticities are generally positive, precisely in accordance with conventional economic theory. In other words, when the wage of the young inexperienced and unskilled group goes up, their employment falls, and the employment of substitutes such as educated workers and older workers increases. Thus, 300,000 young unskilled workers will lose their jobs, but some skilled and older workers will gain, so the overall loss of jobs is reduced to 160,000. Increasing the minimum wage to the living wage change would thus enable the older, better educated workers to gain at the expense of unskilled youth, as happens in France, but of course with serious long-term consequences for those trapped outside the labour market. The current dark situation for Britain’s unskilled youth is shown in Tables 2 and 3, covering the period since the minimum wage began. Table 2 shows that labourforce participation has declined for all the disadvantaged groups except the disabled (whose participation remains low). Admittedly it appears that our youth participation rate is still better than that in France. But the UK lags on another measure which is shown in Table 3, the percent of 15-19s in the not in education, employment or training (NEET) group. Here we see that the UK’s percentage has been growing and at 9.5 % is the worst of the five major economies shown, and worse than the OECD average. In summary, Tables 2 and 3 show that the inequality of life chances has been growing, despite the Low Pay Commission’s mission to reduce “inequity in the workplace”. People who reject the orthodox explanation for the small UK minimum wage effects need an alternative, They bring forward ideas of single buyer power (i.e., “monopsony” – see Manning 2013), or of “efficiency wages” (Leonard et al 2014) to explain
  • 9. the perceived market failure. Ironically, these two theories have diametrically opposed views of what happens in free markets. The monopsony theory implies that wages are too low: firms operate with unfilled vacancies, because raising wages enough to eliminate the backlog would require pay increases for all. But the efficiency wage theory implies that wages are in a sense “too high”: wages are above the market-clearing rate because paying well is a cheap way to help supervisors generate extra employee effort. In fact neither theory fits well with the UK firm size structure which is shown in Table 4. We see that the UK has 3.6 million enterprises which only employ the owner, and obviously have no monopsony power or difficulty with supervision. There are also 1.2 million enterprises which employ workers, but the vast majority of these, 97%, employ fewer than 50 workers, and again can have no monopsony power or supervision issues. In fact, it is only the 6 thousand firms that employ more than 250 to which these theories might apply. However, these firms tend to pay higher wages in any case and so the minimum wage is broadly irrelevant for them. It is much more likely that unskilled and inexperienced workers lose from the minimum, and indeed their unemployment rises more than proportionately as the minimum rises, as shown in Gorry’s (2013) elegant model Monopsony and efficiency wage theories would seem irrelevant here. International Evidence It is fair to say that the UK evidence on the minimum wage does not find large employment effects. It does find some disturbing trends. However, the background to the UK’s minimum wage ensures that any statistical analysis is likely to lead to inconclusive results. For a more successful analysis, we need to look at countries where there is high variation of the minimum either for regions within a country, as in Canada or the USA, or at the variation provided by cross-country panels. A country
  • 10. with low welfare payments (e.g. the US) is also easier to analyse. Let us consider first Canadian and US results, and then examine South Africa which starkly underlines how minimum wages can be misused by skilled workers to cut out unskilled competition.[footnoteRef:3] [3: Another interesting country to consider could be France with its exceptionally high minimum (Gorry 2013). But France presents the same problems as the UK, that is, lack of within-country variation, plus the confounders of high welfare payments and high taxes. China is also a possibility, with good variation provided by different minimum wages in different cities. Fang and Lin (2013) provide evidence of strong negative minimum wage effects using city data which are better than the province data used by Wang and Gunderson (2012) who find inconclusive effects at least for Eastern China. However, China is too early to draw conclusions from yet, since it is so large and heterogeneous with complications of migrant labour and a large state-owned sector. There is also research on minimum wages in LDCs in general, bringing in non-compliance issues in the informal sector, which we will touch on below. ] Canada provides one of the best conditions for research into the effects of minimum wages, since the ten Canadian provinces have different minimum wage policies, sometimes with considerable bite. Good time series data are also available. A convincing body of Canadian literature has thus built up, starting with Baker et al’s (1999) study of 9 provinces over 1975-1993. This study finds that a 10% increase in the minimum reduces teenage employment by 2.5%, and that it takes 6 years for the full effect to be revealed. Canadian data are also used in the recent study for 1997-2008 by Campolieti et al (2014, 587), who find a short-run elasticity of -0.16 for the 15-24 year group. Importantly, they note that their method cannot capture long-run minimum wage effects (since they
  • 11. follow individuals for only 6 months), and recommend doubling this elasticity to derive the full picture. This would lead to a long run elasticity of demand for labour of about -0.3, meaning that a 10% increase in the minimum wage would reduce employment by about 3% among the affected group. A similar finding for teen employment is made by Sen et al (2011). Interestingly, older workers’ employment appears to increase with minimum wage increases (Fang and Gunderson 2009), suggesting they are substituted for less productive youths, as we have already seen for the UK. The minimum’s adverse effect using good data thus becomes clearer. A possible reason for the clarity of the Canadian effect is that Canada’s minimum wage workers tend more to be in the tradeable goods, exporting sectors. In this situation, a higher minimum quickly undermines competitiveness and causes employment reduction. The position is different if minimum wage workers are concentrated in non-tradeable activities such as retailing or construction (as in the UK). In this case, a rise in the minimum wage simply “takes wages out of competition” and this result can even be advantageous, especially for large firms (see Cox and Oaxaca 1982, more recently Neumark and Wascher 2008). Costs go up, but the increase is faced by everyone, and prices can increase to offset this given the absence of overseas competition. This factor might account for the weaker disemployment results found in the US studies (e.g. Addison et al 2012) of the restaurant sector noted below. Magruder’s (2013) study of minimum wages in Indonesia emphasises the importance of whether the sectors mainly affected are in the tradeable or non-tradeable sectors. Turning to research on the US, there is now much technical controversy raised by the work of Allegretto et al (2011) and Dube et al (2010), well summarised in the recent work by Neumark et al (2014). The key problem is how to specify control groups, whether by allowing for state-specific trends, or
  • 12. by using contiguous states, which need not be good controls since cross-border counties might not experience the same shocks. Still, Neumark et al’s exhaustive analysis (2014, p627) concludes that, when the time trends are correctly specified, the elasticity of teen employment to the minimum wage remains in or near the -0.1 to -0.2 range. Elasticity of employment in the restaurant sector is lower, but still negative and significant at around -0.05 or -0.06 (2014, p644). Thus the adverse effect remains. We cannot leave US minimum wage research without mentioning the famous but weak Card and Krueger (1995) studies of the response of fast-food restaurant employment to increases in minimum wages. The best-known of these studies is the contrast of New Jersey with Pennsylvania (which had no increase in the minimum wage). This research is the basis for stating that the conventional economic view that minimum wages cause unemployment is a “myth”. But the New Jersey versus Pennsylvania study is only based on 4 datapoints. The fact that there are many restaurants in the 4 samples (New Jersey before and after, and the control, Pennsylvania before and after) is no help since the same minimum wage regime applies in each. It is also worth noting that again we have the restaurant sector, which is sheltered from international competition, and so should have smaller employment reactions. The work is sold as “a powerful new challenge to the conventional view”, but it is misleading. The evidence from South Africa shows what happens when minimum wages really go wrong. South Africa under white control, before 1994, had what it described as a “civilised labour policy” aiming to favour white employment (Van der Horst 1942, 250; also Siebert 1986). A pillar of this policy was high minimum wages and extended collective agreements which meant that only white workers, who were generally better educated than non-white workers, could gain employment.
  • 13. Minimum wages were thus used as a weapon against the majority. The higher costs that resulted were not so much of a problem when it came to employment because tariff barriers prevented imports competing with domestic businesses. The high minimum wage system continues to this day with extended collective agreements in particular supporting a strongly unionised African labour elite (Schultz 1998). For example, a union worker in manufacturing receives 70% more than a non- union worker (Schultz 1998, p700). The system has since been extended to agriculture and domestic service. In agriculture the pay increase has been large (Bhorat et all 2012), 17%, and employment has contracted considerably, by 14%. In domestic service, again protected from international competition, the effects might not have been so bad (Dinkelman 2012, Hertz 2005), but only 25% of households appear to comply. Thus, we see a policy originally designed to hurt African workers is now being carried forward by African politicians and unions themselves, and still hurting African workers. Finally, let us consider the evidence from international cross- country panels. This research design gives the most variation in minimum wages, and thus helps create more robust studies. Negative employment effects from minimum wages are clear in all the studies. Admittedly there are some difficulties of comparability. In particular, countries such as Germany, Italy, Denmark and Sweden have no national minimum wage as such, but use legally enforceable extended collective agreements. Still, such agreements are effective minima (see below). There is also the difficulty of allowing for widely different welfare regimes, and these studies typically use the OECD’s index of gross benefit replacement rates which leaves out housing benefit that are important in the UK[footnoteRef:4]. However, hopefully the gross replacement rates capture the trends, and in any case the studies all control for country and time fixed effects. [4: Hence Addison and Ozturk’s (2012, Table 2b) replacement rate for the UK averages only 20%, much lower
  • 14. than the actual 60% shown in Table 1 above.] Neumark and Wascher (2004) provide the first comprehensive treatment, analysing 17 OECD countries over the period 1975- 2000. Their main finding (2004, p243) is that the minimum wage elasticity of teenage (15-19) employment is significantly negative, in the -0.2 to -0.4 range. More recently there have been OECD-based international studies by Dolton and Bondiabene (2012) of youth employment, and Addison and Ozturk (2012) of female employment. Dolton and Bondiabene (2012) also find a large negative effect of minimum wages for youth employment, with an elasticity of -0.3 to -0.4, most of this result coming in recession as might be expected. Addison and Ozturk (2012, Table 4) find a negative effect for the adult female employment-to-population rate, with an elasticity of - 0.14 in the short run, and more in the long run when lagged effects are taken into account. Interestingly, there is an indication in this study (2012, Table 7) that the elasticity is larger (-0.34) in countries and time periods when employment protection law (EPL) is strict, as we would expect (see below). Thus, there is an unambiguous picture of strong negative minimum wage effects on lower-productivity groups in the international panel-based literature, which provides arguably the best foundation for research. Collectively set minimum wages Collectively set minimum wages arise when a collective agreement is extended by law to third parties within an industry or sector. A detailed set of minimum wages (and conditions) covering many job types and levels is thereby established for the industry or sector. Martins (2014) shows how the process works in the case of Portugal. Such extensions are the result of so-called “erga omnes” (towards others) regulations, and have the aim of reducing non-union low-wage competition. They are common (see Murtin et al 2014) in countries where the unions
  • 15. are politically powerful – for example, are part-funded or privileged by the state as in Greece or France or South Africa – but where local union power is low (again, France and Greece[footnoteRef:5]). In these circumstances, unions have the power to bring about these regulations and also need to, since non-union firms are so prevalent. The picture is given in Table 5, where we see that France, Spain, Portugal, Germany and Italy all have high use of extensions arrangements. The important point is that erga omnes regulations enable the setting of detailed minimum wage floors, floors that are determined by big business and labour in the capital cities – Athens, Rome, Paris – with little concern for conditions in the provinces. Hence, a straitjacket of minimum wages is thrown over the country. [5: The UK used to have an erga omnes arrangement for unions to petition for extension of their agreements, but Thatcher dismantled it (see Addison and Siebert 2000) with the 1980 Employment Act. The “fair wages resolution” requiring government contractors to observe terms no less favourable than those obtaining under collective agreements was also dropped at this time.] Research on this type of minimum wage setting builds on the literature of union power raising unemployment, which of course has long been controversial because of the many factors that influence unemployment. Steven Nickell’s (1997) famous study of unemployment in OECD countries in the 1980s and 1990s shows union agreement coverage strongly raising unemployment, but his “bargaining coordination” variable washes out this effect, suggesting that cooperation between the two sides of industry (corporatism) could engender responsible unionism. Recent work on these lines is reported in the OECD’s (2011b, p152) study of inequality using the OECD panel of countries over 1984-2007. Here there is shown to be a well-determined negative effect of collective bargaining coverage on employment rates. High tax rates and employment
  • 16. protection legislation hurt too. The most recent work using the OECD panel is by Murtin et al (2014) with a more extensive model, this time of unemployment. Their main innovation is to use collective agreement coverage extension, as shown in Table 5, which they find interacts with taxes (also shown in Table 5) to raise unemployment. Their minimum wage variable also raises unemployment, again more so when taxes are high. These interaction results can be explained with the aid of Figure 3. Again we have the conventional demand (D) and supply (S) curves for unskilled labour, and start with a no-tax equilibrium at E1. Now, assume a tax is imposed, so that the net demand curve for labour shifts inwards to D|net tax as shown. Without the minimum wage or collective agreement floor, the new equilibrium would be at E2 with a lower wage, and less employment (but no disequilibrium unemployment). However, if there is a wage floor, the wage cannot fall so much, and the employment fall to B is greater, as shown. At B there is also disequilibrium unemployment. Therefore, according to this simple model a rise in tax sweeps more into the minimum wage and extended collective agreement net, causing unemployment. The empirical results support this theoretical observation. There are also instructive results from two country case studies of Portugal and Greece involving extended agreements. As can be seen from Table 5, both of these countries have used such agreements extensively, though they are now restricted by recent debt bailout agreements[footnoteRef:6]. Martins’ (2014) analysis of Portugal over 2007-11 links unemployment to extensions of agreements to non-parties, and shows that average employment levels in affected sectors drop by 2% in the four months following extensions, as firms stop hiring, and close down. Since the wage increase is 2% to 4%, the implied elasticity is between -0.5 and -1 (Martins 2014, 14). Peripheral employment of temporary workers and sub-contractors meanwhile increases, as we would expect. This temporary
  • 17. worker result is the same as that for the Greek study (Anagnostopoulos and Siebert 2013), based on a survey of 200 provincial firms, which finds that low-paying firms, near the minimum, are more likely to employ temporary workers. The Greek study also shows that these effects persist even though many Greek firms do not in fact pay the minimum they remain small so as to avoid the attentions of the labour inspectorate. The minimum wage and extended collective agreements coupled with high taxes thus not only reduce employment, but also push firms to be too small[footnoteRef:7]. [6: In Greece for example (see Commission 2014 p49 and LABREF database), the government in 2011 and 2012 agreed to reduce minimum pay rates by 22% (32% for young people). It also agreed to suspend extension of occupational and sector collective agreements, and to allow firm-level agreements which could be less favourable than the sector-level agreement. According to IndustriALL (2014) measures such as this caused Greek sector agreements to fall from 65 to 14 in 2013, and in Portugal (Martins 2014), coverage fell from 1.8 million in 2008 to 290,000 in 2012.] [7: Thus in Greece and Portugal firms are too small, with only 5% employing more than 10 people, compared to an OECD average of 15% employing more than 10 (see OECD, 2011c). Alternatively, if policing of the extended agreements is effective, as in South Africa, small firms can be prevented from growing enough (see Magruder 2012). The point is, regulation breeds regulation.] Conclusions and thoughts on real help for the unskilled Mnimum wages do have adverse employment effects broadly in line with conventional economic models. UK studies generally find small effects, but the UK environment is poorly suited to measure such effects given the changes in welfare benefits, and the lack of regional variation. Matters become clearer when we turn to more suitable empirical settings which provide clear evidence of an adverse effects of minimum wages on
  • 18. employment. Better ways to help the poor involve raising skills or, in the shorter term before such policies take meaningful effect, the provision of wage subsidies through the welfare system. When it comes to raising skills, the family is crucial, together with education. In fact, Table 6 shows that comparable countries all have difficulties with families in poor circumstances, so the UK is not alone. Admittedly, the first two rows show that the UK has exceptionally high numbers of children in single parent and workless households (see Kristian Niemietz 2012). Yet while Italy does best on this criterion, as can be seen, it lags otherwise. The intergenerational earnings correlation is 0.48 in the UK which is high[footnoteRef:8], but no worse than in Italy or the US. Moreover, inequality in disposable household incomes, as measured by the Gini coefficient, is broadly similar at around 0.30 to 0.34 in all the countries. Only the US stands out as particularly unequal, but this result is to be expected since the US is much larger and more heterogeneous. [8: Here we correlate the incomes of fathers and sons. A low correlation as in Germany, 0.32, is better because it shows that good parental circumstances have less effect in improving the child’s life chances than in the UK which has a much higher correlation.] Furthermore, taking adult language proficiency which is an important measure of skill, we see a distinct gradient according to family background, as is to be expected. Individuals from advantaged backgrounds (having at least one parent with a university degree) score about 1 point higher on a 1 to 5 scale than the less advantaged. All the comparator countries have an almost exactly similar effect, which points once again to the fact that this problem is deep-seated. Encouragement of stable families and better, less unionised and more competitive school systems is difficult, but they are important policy priorities.
  • 19. High welfare simply makes matters worse in the long term, as well described by Charles Murray (1984, 2012). A quick and well-targeted way of helping the working poor is by subsidising low paid work, a policy which contradicts the minimum wage. People have their earnings topped up by the tax payer, and are therefore prepared to work for less, which expands their job opportunities. In fact, such a policy has been in place in the UK ever since 1999 when the Working Families Tax Credit was introduced (Azhmat 2006), modelled on the US Earned Income Tax Credit, and since expanded with Working Tax Credit (see Bourne and Shackleton 2014). Figure 4 shows how the policy works by reducing the wage that the employer pays from W* to WL. The equilibrium on the original demand curve moves to point A, to which is added the subsidy, and the worker receives the higher gross wage, WH.= WL+SUB. It is important that the wage the employer pays is allowed to fall, though, and if the minimum wage prevents this fall, the policy will not work, and we remain at C. In a sense, the employer has to be paid some of the subsidy and his/her profits will increase which has disturbed some commentators (e.g. Gregg et al 2012). However, the result is more jobs which is what we want. Tax credits conditional on work currently encourage about 2.5 million workers to work (see Browne and Hood 2012), but they only account for about 5% of the amount paid out to working age welfare recipients, and are dwarfed in particular by child tax credits and housing benefits. Reform is needed to make working tax credits more important (see Bourne and Shackleton 2014). This said, the way they lower wages (see Azmat 2006 and Hotz and Scholz 2000) is exactly as predicted by our conventional labour market analysis. In conclusion, there is no need for analysts (e.g. Holmlund 2014, or Schmitt 2013) to worry about “discernible effects" of minimum wages on employment. The effects are discernible,
  • 20. when properly measured. Hence it is indeed probable that the UK’s dismal youth labour market performance since 1999 is partly attributable to the imposition of the minimum wage – interacting with high tax rates. This is also the case with the poorly functioning youth labour markets of Portugal and Greece, and others such as France and South Africa. Moreover, the way in which more skilled workers displace the less skilled, and temporary workers displace permanent workers is also in line with conventional economic models. Obviously, in a political world which denies productivity differences – including skills, gender, age and disability differences[footnoteRef:9] – the differential effects of minimum wages are politically unwelcome This is all the more reason for economists to stick to their guns and look for real, not fake, ways to help the poor. [9: The disability pressure groups often do the disabled no favours. For example, (LPC 2005 p124), Mothercare for Children in Hospital Ltd (MCCH) cooed: “ the minimum wage is a positive step to reducing stigma, discrimination and workplace exploitation…it has acted as a catalyst to change” etc etc. But Shaw Employment Services is blunt: ”Both client and provider are finding that instead of being more able to help the disabled achieve employment, the Government, through the NMW, has inadvertently created the first barrier” (LPC 2003, p105).] References Addison, J., M. Blackburn and C. Cotti (2012), “Labour Market Outcomes: County-Level Estimates from the Restaurant-and-Bar Sector”, British Journal of Industrial Relations, 50: 412-435. Addison, J. and O. Ozturk (2012), “Minimum Wages, Labor Market Institutions, and Female Employment: A Cross-Country Analysis”, Industrial and Labor Relations Review, 65: 779-809. Addison, J. and W. Stanley Siebert (1994), “Recent Developments in Social Policy in the New European Union”,
  • 21. Industrial and Labor Relations Review, 48:5-27. Addison J and W. S. Siebert (2000), "Labor Market Reform in the UK: from Thatcher to Blair", Journal of Private Enterprise, 15: 1-34. Allegretto, S., A. Dube, and M. Reich. (2011), “Do Minimum Wages Really Reduce Teen Employment? Accounting for heterogeneity and selectivity in state panel data. Industrial Relations50: 205–40. Azmat, G. (2006), “The Incidence of an Earned Income Tax Credit: Evaluating the Impact on Wages in the UK”, London School of Economics, CEP Discussion Paper 724. Anagnostopoulos A. and W. S. Siebert (2012), “The impact of Greek labour market regulation on temporary and family employment - Evidence from a new survey”, IZA Discussion Paper 6504. Baker, M., D. Benjamin and S. Stanger (1999). “The Highs and Lows of the Minimum Wage Effect: A Time-Series Cross- Section Study of the Canadian Law”, Journal of Labor Economics, 17:18-50. Baum, C. (2006), An Introduction to Modern Econometrics Using Stata, College Station, Texas: Stata Press. Bhorat, H., R. Kanbur and B. Stanwix (2013), “Estimating the Impact of Minimum Wages on Employment, Wages and Nonwage Benefits: The Case of Agriculture in South Africa”, Cornell University, School of Applied Economics and Management, WP 2013-05. Bourne, R. and J. Shackleton (2014), “The Minimum Wage: Silver Bullet or Poisoned Chalice”, Institute of Economic Affairs Briefing 14.01. Brown J. and A. Hood (2012), A Survey of the UK Benefit System, IFS Briefing Note BN13, London: Institute for Fiscal Studies. Campolieti, M., M. Gunderson and B. Lee (2014), “Minimum Wage Effects On Permanent Versus Temporary Minimum Wage Employment”, Contemporary Economic Policy, 32: 578-591. Card, D., and A. Krueger (1995). Myth and Measurement: the
  • 22. New Economics of the Minimum wage, Princeton: Princeton University Press. Commission (2006), Green Paper—Modernising labour law to meet the challenges of the 21st century, Brussels 22.11.2006 COM(2006) 708 final. Commission (2014), “The Second Economic Adjustment Programme for Greece”, Occasional Papers, No. 192, April, Brussels: Directorate-General for Economic and Financial Affairs . Corak, M., (2013), Income Inequality, Equality of Opportunity, and Intergenerational Mobility, Journal of Economic Perspectives, 27: 79-102. Cox, J. and R. Oaxaca (1982), ‘The political economy of minimum wage legislation”, Economic Inquiry, 20: 533-50. Dickens, R., R. Riley and D. Wilkinson, (2012), “Re-examining the Impact of the National Minimum Wage on Earnings, Employment and Hours: the Importance of Recession and Firm Size”, University of Sussex and National Institute of Economic and Social Research. http://www.sheffield.ac.uk/polopoly_fs/1.247213!/file/E1_riley. pdf Dinkelman T. and V. Ranchod (2012), “Evidence on the impact of minimum wage laws in an informal sector: Domestic workers in South Africa”, Journal of Development Economics, 99: 27- 45. Dolton, Peter and Chiara Bondibene (2012), “The International Experience of Minimum Wages in an Economic Downturn”, Economic Policy, 27: 99-142. Dube, A., T. Lester, and M. Reich. (2010), Minimum Wage Effects Across State Borders: Estimates using contiguous counties. Review of Economics and Statistics92: 945–64. Fang, T. and M. Gunderson (2009), “Minimum Wage Impacts on Older Workers: Longitudinal Estimates from Canada”, British Journal of Industrial Relations, 47: 371-87. Fang T., and C. Lin (2013), “Minimum Wages and Employment in China”, IZA Discussion Paper 7813.
  • 23. Godfrey, S., J. Theron and M. Visser (2007), The State of Collective Bargaining in South Africa, UCT: Development Policy Research Unit Research Paper 07/130 Gorry, A. (2013), “Minimum wages and youth unemployment”, European Economic Review 64: 57-75. Gregg, P., A. Hurrell and M. Whittaker (2012), Creditworthy – Assessing the Impact of Tax Credits, London: Resolution Foundation. Hertz, T. (2005), “The Effect of Minimum Wages on the Employment and Earnings of South Africa's Domestic Service Workers, Upjohn Institute Working Paper 05-120. Holmlund, B. (2014), “What do labor market institutions do?”, Labour Economics 30: 62-69. Hotz, V. and J. Scholtz (2000), “Not Perfect, but Still Pretty Good: The EITC and Other Policies to Support the US Low- Wage Labour Market”, OECD Economic Studies 31. IndustriALL (2014), “Negotiating our future!”, Collective Bargaining and Social Policy Conference, Vienna, http://www.industriall- europe.eu/committees/CB/2014/Increasing%20cover%20rate- EN.pdf Kay L. (2010), Escaping the Poverty Trap, London: Policy Exchange. Krugman, P. (1994), “Past and Prospective Causes of High Unemployment”, Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City, http://www.kc.frb.org/publicat/econrev/pdf/4q94krug.pdf Leonard, M., T. Stanley and H. Doucouliagos (2014), “Does the UK MinimumWage Reduce Employment? A Meta-Regression Analysis”, British Journal of Industrial Relations, 52: 499-520. Living Wage Commission (2014), Work That Pays, London: Joseph Rowntree Trust. LPC (2014), Low Pay Commission Report 2014, Cm 8816, London: Low Pay Commission. LPC (2005), Low Pay Commission Report 2005, Cm 6475, London: Low Pay Commission. LPC (2003), Low Pay Commission Report 2003 – Building on
  • 24. Success, London: Low Pay Commission. LPC (2001), The National Minimum Wage – Making a Difference, Volume 1, Cm 5075, London: Low Pay Commission. Magruder, J (2013), “Can Minimum Wages Cause a Big Push? Evidence from Indonesia”, Journal of Development Economics, 100: 48-62. Magruder (2012), High Unemployment Yet Few Small Firms: The Role of Centralized Bargaining in South Africa”, American Economic Journal: Applied Economics, 4: 138-166. Manning A. (2013), “Minimum Wages: A View from the UK”, Perspektiven der Wirtschaftspolitik, 14: 57–66. Martins, P. (2014) “30,000 Minimum Wages: The Economic Effects of Collective Bargaining Extensions”, IZA Discussion Paper 8540. Murray C. (1984), Losing Ground: American Social Policy 1950-1980, New York: Basic Books. Murray C. (2012), Coming Apart: The State of Whate America 1960-2010, New York: Crown Forum. Murtin, F., A. de Serres and A. Hijzen (2014), “Unemployment and the coverage extension of collective wag eagreements”, European Economic Review, 71: 52-66. Neumark, D., J. Salas and W. Wascher (2014), “Revisiting the Minimum Wage-Employment Debate: Throwing Out the Baby with the Bathwater?”, Industrial and Labor Relations Review, 67 (supplement): 608-48. Neumark, D. and W. Wascher (2008), “Minimum Wages and Low-Wage Workers: How Well Does Reality Match the Rhetoric?”, Minnesota Law Review, 92: 1296-1316. Neumark, D., and W.Wascher, 2004. “Minimum Wages, Labor Market Institutions and Youth Unemployment: A Cross- National Analysis”, Industrial and Labor Relations Review, 57: 223-48. Nickell, S. (1997), “Unemployment and Labor Market Rigidities: Europe versus North America”, Journal of Economic Perspectives, 11: 55-74. Riley, R. (2013), “Modelling Demand for Low Skilled/Low Paid
  • 25. Labour: Exploring The Employment Trade-Offs of a Living Wage”, NIESR Discussion Paper 404 Niemietz, K. (2012), Redefining the Poverty Debate, London: Institute of Economic Affairs. OECD (2014), Education at a Glance 2014: OECD Indicators, OECD Publishing, http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/eag-2014-en OECD (2011), Doing Better for Families Paris: OECD Publishing DOI:10.1787/9789264098732-en OECD (2011), Divided We Stand: Why Inequality Keeps Rising, Paris: OECD Publishing. http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/9789264119536-en Sen, A., K. Rybzynski and C. Van De Waal (2011), “Teen Employment, Poverty, and the Minimum Wage: Evidence from Canada”, Labour Economics, 18: 36-47 Schmitt, J. (2013). “Why Does the Minimum Wage Have No Discernible Effect on Employment?”, Washington: Center for Economic and Policy Research Schultz, T. and G. Mwabu (1998), “Labor Unions and the Distribution of Wages and Employment in South Africa”, Industrial and Labor Relations Review, 51: 680-703. Siebert W. S. (2014), “The Living Wage”, Economic Affairs Magazine, Summer: 18-21. Siebert W. S. (2013), “The Wage Flaw – Why Minimum Pay Isn’t Working”, Economic Affairs Magazine, Summer: 4-7. Siebert, W. S. (1986), “Restrictive Practices in South Africa’s Labour Market”, Economic Affairs, October-November: 26-29. Van der Horst, S. (1942), Native Labour in South Africa, London: Frank Cass. Visser J. (2013), Wage Bargaining Institutions - from crisis to crisis, Brussels, Directorate-General for Economic and Financial Affairs: Economic Papers 488. Wang, J. and M. Gunderson (2012), “Minimum wage effects on employment and wages: dif-in-dif estimates from eastern China”, International Journal of Manpower, 33: 860-876.
  • 26. Table 1: Net replacement rates over 60 Months unemployment France Germany United States UK No child 2 child No child 2 child No child 2 child No child 2 child 2001 60.3 70.3 59.6 73.5 15.2 43.0 55.0 64.9 2012 53.6 63.2 49.9 70.4 24.8 42.8 51.0 72.4 Change 2012-2001 -6.7 -7.1
  • 27. -9.7 -3.0 9.6 -0.2 -4.0 7.5 Source: OECD Benefits and Wages: Statisticshttp://www.oecd.org/els/benefitsandwagesstatistics.ht m (NRR_Over5years_EN) Notes: Replacement rates are calculated based on incomes after any tax and social security contributions have been deducted, and any cash benefits received. Family qualifies for cash housing assistance and social assistance "top ups". The figures give unweighted averages relative to full-time earnings levels of 67% and 100% of average worker earnings. (Prior to 2001 only gross rates not including housing assistance are available.) Table 2: Adverse Changes in Employment for Unskilled Workers Labourforce participation rate (% of the population in each group) All working age No qualific-ations Disabled people 18-20 yrs old 16-24 yrs old France 15-24 2000 71.7 50.8 37.7 61.2
  • 28. 69.7 35.6 2013 71.6 42.6 42.1 47.0 61.7 37.6 Change 2013-2000 -0.1 -8.2 4.4 -14.2 -8.0 2.0 Sources: Commission (2014, Table 2.11), and OECD Employment Outlook (2014) Table 3: NEETs – Country Trends (% of 15-19 year olds not in education, employment or training) France Germany Italy United States UK OECD average 1997 2.9 5.0 15.2 7.1 8.0
  • 29. 9.2 2012 6.9 3.0 12.0 7.7 9.5 7.6 Change 2012-1997 4.0 -2.0 -3.2 0.6 1.5 -1.6 Sources: OECD Education at a Glance (2014), Chart C5.3, and OECD Doing Better for Families (2011), Figure 1.15 Table 4: Firm Size and Employment, UK 2009 Number - Private Sector, 2009 (including pub corps and nationalised bodies) Enterprises (000) Employees (mill.) Enterprises. without employees 3620 0 Enterprises with employees 1220 18.2 Enterprise sizes: 1-4
  • 30. 795 1.8 5-49 390 4.6 50-249 30 2.6 250-499 3 1.0 500 or more 3 8.1 MEMO Central and local govt 5 5.4 Non-profit 84 1.9 Source: BIS, Enterprise Directorate, 2010, http://stats.bis.gov.uk/ed/sme/SMEStats2009.xls#'UK Whole Economy'!A1 Notes: An enterprise is the smallest group of legal units which has autonomy. It is based on the Interdepartmental Business Register (IDBR) formed from VAT or PAYE records collected by HMRC. Since the VAT threshold (£67k in 09) excludes small firms, estimates of their numbers are then added using Labourforce Survey figures of numbers of self-employed
  • 31. (4.1m). Private households and temp agencies are excluded.. There is no lower bound for inclusion as an enterprise, hence the smallest amount of enterprise activity counts – hence there are many "no employee" enterprises which have only working proprietors in the business. “Employees” have a contract of employment, and include part-timers. Working proprietors are self employed (but working directors of companies are counted as employees). Table 5: Collectively Set Minimum Wages, early 2000s Can Den Fra Ger Gre Ita Nor Por SA Spain Swe UK US Coverage* extension 4 0 79 48 30 46 15 49
  • 32. 10 57 1 9 4 Use of erga omnes clauses No No High High High High Some High Some High No No No Union density 31 75 9 28 30 34 56 25 25 15 81 34 14 Govt rev % GDP 40 55
  • 33. 50 45 38 47 57 40 27 36 54 40 31 Sources: Murtins et al (2014), Industriall Global Union (2014) http://www.industriall- europe.eu/committees/CB/2014/Increasing%20cover%20rate- EN.pdf; Visser (2013), Godfrey (2007), OECD Government at a Glance (2013, Table 3.11. Notes: * coverage extension measured as collective agreement coverage minus percentage unionisation Table 6: Inequalities – Country Comparisons France Germany Italy United States UK % children (0-18) in single-parent households, 2007a 14 15 10 22 26 % children (0-14) living in jobless households, 2011b 10 7
  • 34. 8 8 19 Intergenerational earnings correlation, late 90sc 0.40 0.32 0.49 0.50 0.48 Gini coefficient of inequality of household disposable incomed 0.29 0.30 0.33 0.37 0.34 Average adult literacy proficiency levele Both parents<upper secondary educ. 2.0 1.8 1.9 1.8 2.1 At least one parent with tertiary educ. 3.0 2.8 2.7 2.9 3.1 Sources: a OECD Doing Better for Families (2011) Table 1.1; b OECD Doing Better for Families (2011) Table LMF1.1.A; c Corak (2013, p82); d OECD Divided We Stand (2011), Fig 6.1. (income is household income, corrected for household size – the Gini coefficient varies between 0 for perfect equality, and 1 for perfect inequality); e OECD Education at a Glance (2014, Chart A4.4) (literacy score is from the OECD programme for
  • 35. International Assessment of Adult Competencies, with proficiency graded from worst (1) to best (5)). ( D S Welfare benefits floor W* A B Unskilled Labour E Minimum wage floor ) Figure 1: Welfare benefits confound minimum wage
  • 36. employment effects Figure 2: Effects of the minimum wage on earnings - 1998 and 1999 compared Source: Low Pay Commission Report 2000, p19 ( Unskilled Labour Minimum wage or collective agreement floor D| gross S W* E 2 B E 1 D| net tax TAX )
  • 37. Figure 3: Minimum wage magnifies disemployment effects of tax ( Unskilled Labour W* SUB D| gross D| plus subsidy S W* W L W H B A Minimum wage or collective agreement floor
  • 38. C ) Figure 4: Subsidising work 5 Leading Change Leading Change
  • 39. Carlos Ghosen was named CEO of Nissan took over the Renault company in April of 2005. The new position would continue to head Nissan as well as Renault. Ghosen was well known for his ability to turn struggling companies into profit driven thriving businesses and that was the hope of the new assignment with Renault. Issues In March of 1999, the ninth carmaker in the world asked Carlos Ghosen to lead as its CEO after a failed merger with Volvo. Nissans strength in product design and manufacturing and Renaults engineering quality made the merger all the more necessary. Renault would help with international expansions and Nissan would get rid of its short-term troubles of poor production portfolio and its diminished brand value. As one of the youngest to head companies of this size, Ghosn knew he had to make an impact, for the Japanese were not accustomed to a dictatorship type of leadership. Therefore, he knew dictating his expectations could lead to low morale, and if too lenient, it could slow change. Therefore, Ghosen brought the need for urgency in operations by mobilizing them. Just as Nissan’s employees were reluctant to except failures and blamed other departments or economic changes on most of the problems, which resulted in the lack of urgency and the resolve to just live with the problems. Ghosen believed that human tendency is to resist change and anything new of different from the status quo. However, he belied by excepting changes, people will be stronger, because they would have a better understanding of the differences and find ways to discover the root cause of the issues. Proposed Solution
  • 40. s Ghosen formed Cross-function teams with employees being directly involved in the process. Doing so helped Ghosen explain his plans and gain acceptance more easily. In these cross-functional teams, the employees were asked to look beyond their responsibilities, and obtain a better understanding of other departments. Once the teams were in place it became much easier for the employees to see and own responsibility whenever something went wrong. Just after appointing the teams, they were asked to submit their plans to achieve the maximum output in each of the areas. By listening to the employees and asking their opinions in the reform process, was monumental in the way Ghosen lead his vision for reform. He avoided impersonal meetings and stressed the importance of face-to-face communications. Once both companies became one, Ghosn choose to promote Transparency, Performance, and Value. Ghosn believed that blending the strengths of the employees at each of the companies, innovation excellence of the French and the dedication towards the manufacturing of the Japanese, which created synergy in purchasing, manufacturing, information systems and platform sharing, but also maintained both companies autonomy by keeping their own brand identities and corporations. Ghosn’s goal was to making the company recognizable by the
  • 41. consumer as one of the best automakers in quality, value, service and generate a total operating profit among all other leading automakers by keeping a high profit margin and continued upward growth. Renault took an equity stake in Nissan with the understanding that Nissan would have the same opertunity at a later time. This would enhance both Renault and Nissan’s performance by creating a community interest and cross shareholdings.Barriers to Change/ Emotional Bonds The differences in culture between the French and Japanese could have been very difficult, however Ghosn kept an open mind focusing on the economic benefits and the turnaround of the company’s. Goshn had to make tough changes such as haying off more than 21,000 people and closing five factories in order to increase Nissans profit margin. He also changed the policy of the lifetime employment and hired more women, which both were frowned upon. Goshn also demanded at least 20% savings from suppliers over a 3-year time period and the ability to use global contractors. Personal reflection I think Goshn took whatever measures necessary to get both companies producing at profitable pace and I think his decisions on were based on that fact, which proved profitable in the end. Conclusion The commitments of the Nissan Revival Plan had been met one year prior to its expected schedule, and the launch of new
  • 42. models was created at a very high rate. Nissans profitability contributed to Renault’s net income and higher profitability and global presence. The President of Nissan was concerned about the complacent nature of Nissan because of poor markets. However, he also expected more flexibility to ensure employees work closer to the consumer’s needs. References Spector, B. (2013). Implementing organizational change: Theory into practice (3rd ed.). Upper Saddle River, NJ: Prentice Hall Leading Change 4 Copyright © 2014 Cengage Learning * * Chapter 17 The Economics of Labour Markets
  • 43. 2.bin Copyright © 2014 Cengage Learning THE MARKET FOR THE FACTORS OF PRODUCTIONFactors of production are the inputs used to produce goods and services. The demand for a factor of production is a derived demand.A firm’s demand for a factor of production is derived from its decision to supply a good in another market. Copyright © 2014 Cengage Learning THE DEMAND FOR LABOURLabour markets, like other markets in the economy, are governed by the forces of supply and demand.Most labour services, rather than being final goods ready to be enjoyed by consumers, are inputs into the production of other goods.
  • 44. Copyright © 2014 Cengage Learning The Production Function and the Marginal Product of Labour The production function illustrates the relationship between the quantity of inputs used and the quantity of output of a good. Copyright © 2014 Cengage Learning Table 1 How the Competitive Firm Decides How Much Labour to Hire Copyright©2014 Cengage Copyright © 2014 Cengage Learning
  • 45. Figure 1 The Production Function Quantity of Apple Pickers 0 Quantity of Apples 300 280 240 180 100 1 2
  • 46. 3 4 5 Copyright©2014 Cengage Production function Copyright © 2014 Cengage Learning The Production Function and the Marginal Product of Labour
  • 47. The marginal product of labour is the increase in the amount of output from an additional unit of labour. MPL = (Q2 – Q1)/(L2 – L1) Copyright © 2014 Cengage Learning The Production Function and the Marginal Product of LabourDiminishing Marginal Product of Labour As the number of workers increases, the marginal product of labour declines. As more and more workers are hired, each additional worker contributes less to production than the prior one. The production function becomes flatter as the number of workers rises. This property is called diminishing marginal product.
  • 48. Copyright © 2014 Cengage Learning The Production Function and the Marginal Product of LabourDiminishing marginal product refers to the property whereby the marginal product of an input declines as the quantity of the input increases. Copyright © 2014 Cengage Learning Figure 1 The Production Function
  • 49. Quantity of Apple Pickers 0 Quantity of Apples 300 280 240 180 100 1 2 3 4 5 Copyright©2014 Cengage Production function
  • 50. Copyright © 2014 Cengage Learning The Value of the Marginal Product and the Demand for LabourThe value of the marginal product is the marginal product of the input multiplied by the market price of the output. Copyright © 2014 Cengage Learning The Value of the Marginal Product and the Demand for Labour
  • 51. The value of the marginal product (also known as marginal revenue product) is measured as a money cost.It diminishes as the number of workers rises because the market price of the good is constant. Copyright © 2014 Cengage Learning The Value of the Marginal Product and the Demand for LabourTo maximize profit, the competitive, profit-maximizing firm hires workers up to the point where the value of the marginal product of labour equals the wage. VMPL = Wage Copyright © 2014 Cengage Learning The Value of the Marginal Product and the Demand for LabourThe value of marginal product curve is the labour
  • 52. demand curve for a competitive, profit-maximizing firm. Copyright © 2014 Cengage Learning Figure 2 The Value of the Marginal Product of Labour 0 Quantity of Apple Pickers 0
  • 53. Value of the Marginal Product Copyright©2014 Cengage Value of marginal product (demand curve for labour) Market wage Profit-maximizing quantity Copyright © 2014 Cengage Learning Input Demand and Output Supply: Two Sides of the Same Coin When a competitive firm hires labour up to the point at which the value of the marginal product equals the wage, it also produces up to the point at which the price equals the marginal
  • 54. cost. Copyright © 2014 Cengage Learning What Causes the Labour Demand Curve to Shift?Output price. A change in the price of the product: An increase raises the value of the marginal product of labour and increases the demand for labour. A decrease lowers the value of the marginal product of labour and decreases the demand for labour. Technological change. Technological advance raises the marginal product of labour, which in turn raises the value of the marginal product of labour. Change in the supply of other factors. Copyright © 2014 Cengage Learning EQUILIBRIUM IN THE LABOUR MARKETThe wage adjusts
  • 55. to balance the supply and demand for labour.The wage equals the value of the marginal product of labour. Copyright © 2014 Cengage Learning Figure 4 Equilibrium in a Labour Market Wage (price of labour)
  • 56. 0 Quantity of labour Copyright©2014 Cengage Supply Demand Equilibrium wage, W Equilibrium employment, L Copyright © 2014 Cengage Learning EQUILIBRIUM IN THE LABOUR MARKETLabour supply and labour demand determine the equilibrium wage.Shifts in the
  • 57. supply or demand curve for labour cause the equilibrium wage to change. Copyright © 2014 Cengage Learning Shifts in Labour SupplyAn increase in the supply of labour : Results in a surplus of labour. Puts downward pressure on wages. Makes it profitable for firms to hire more workers. Results in diminishing marginal product. Lowers the value of the marginal product. Gives a new equilibrium. Copyright © 2014 Cengage Learning Figure 6 A Shift in Labour Supply
  • 59. 2. . . . reduces the wage . . . 3. . . . and raises employment. 1. An increase in labour supply . . . S W L W L
  • 60. Copyright © 2014 Cengage Learning Shifts in Labour DemandAn increase in the demand for labour : Makes it profitable for firms to hire more workers. Puts upward pressure on wages. Raises the value of the marginal product. Gives a new equilibrium. Copyright © 2014 Cengage Learning Figure 7 A Shift in Labour Demand
  • 61. Wage (price of labour) 0 Quantity of labour Copyright©2014 Cengage Supply Demand, D 2. . . . increases the wage . . .
  • 62. 3. . . . and increases employment. D W L W L 1. An increase in labour demand . . .
  • 63. Copyright © 2014 Cengage Learning MonopsonyDefinition of a monopsony: a market with a single buyer. A monopsony is in many ways similar to a monopoly. A monopsony employer will take into account that fact that the supply curve for labour represents the average cost of labour. (See figure 8) The monopsony will employ fewer workers and at a lower rate. Copyright © 2014 Cengage Learning Figure 8 The Wage Rate and Employment Level in a Monopsony
  • 64. Copyright©2014 Cengage Copyright © 2014 Cengage Learning WAGE DIFFERENTIALSWhat causes earnings to vary? Wages are governed by labour supply and labour demand. Labour demand reflects the marginal productivity of labour. In equilibrium, each worker is paid the value of his or her marginal contribution to the economy’s production of goods and services. Copyright © 2014 Cengage Learning WAGE DIFFERENTIALSCauses
  • 65. Compensating differentials Human capital Ability, effort, and chance Signalling The superstar phenomenon Copyright © 2014 Cengage Learning 1. Compensating Differentials Compensating differential refers to a difference in wages that arises from non-monetary characteristics of different jobs. Coal miners are paid more than others with similar levels of education. Night shift workers are paid more than day shift workers. University professors are paid less than lawyers and doctors. Copyright © 2014 Cengage Learning
  • 66. 2. Human Capital Human capital is the accumulation of investments in people, such as education and on-the-job training. The most important type of human capital is education. Firms are willing to pay more for highly educated workers because highly educated workers have higher marginal products. Copyright © 2014 Cengage Learning 3. Ability, Effort, and Chance People differ in their: Physical and mental attributes. This will affect their productivity level and therefore their wage. Level of work effort. Those who work hard are more productive and earn a higher wage.Chance also plays a role in determining wages
  • 67. Copyright © 2014 Cengage Learning 4. Alternative View of Education: SignallingFirms use educational attainment as a way of sorting between high-ability and low-ability workers. It is rational for firms to interpret a university degree as a signal of ability. Copyright © 2014 Cengage Learning 5. The Superstar PhenomenonSuperstars arise in markets that exhibit the following characteristics: Every customer in the market wants to enjoy the good supplied by the best producer. The good is produced with a technology that makes it possible for the best producer to supply every customer at a low cost.
  • 68. Copyright © 2014 Cengage Learning Above-Equilibrium Wages: Minimum-Wage Laws, Unions, and Efficiency WagesWhy are some workers’ wages set above the level that brings supply and demand into equilibrium? Minimum wage laws Market power of labour unions Efficiency wages Copyright © 2014 Cengage Learning 1. Minimum wagesThe market for labour looks like any other market: The equilibrium price is the wage and equilibrium quantity is the labour hired.Introducing a minimum wage. If the minimum wage is above the equilibrium wage in the labour market, a surplus of labour will develop (unemployment). (See figure 9) The minimum wage will be a binding constraint only in markets
  • 69. where equilibrium wages are low. Thus, the minimum wage will have its greatest impact on the market for teenagers and unskilled workers. Copyright © 2014 Cengage Learning Figure 9a How the Minimum Wage Affects the Labour Market Copyright©2014 Cengage
  • 70. Copyright © 2014 Cengage Learning Figure 9b How the Minimum Wage Affects the Labour Market Copyright©2014 Cengage Copyright © 2014 Cengage Learning 1. Minimum wages Advocates for a minimum wage argue that
  • 71. raising the standard of living of the working poor outweighs any potential increase in unemployment. Opponents argue there are better ways or combating poverty since: A minimum wage raises unemployment Some of those on a minimum wage are second earners in households. Those poor not in work do not gain the benefit. Copyright © 2014 Cengage Learning Figure 9a
  • 72. Copyright©2014 Cengage Copyright © 2014 Cengage Learning 2. The market Power of UnionsUnions often raise wages above the level that would prevail without a union.A union is a worker association that bargains with employers over wages and working conditions.A strike refers to the organized withdrawal of labour from a firm by a union. Copyright © 2014 Cengage Learning 3. Efficiency Wages The theory of efficiency wages holds that a firm can find it profitable to pay high wages because doing so increases the productivity of its workers. High wages may: Reduce worker turnover. Increase worker effort.
  • 73. Raise the quality of workers that apply for jobs at the firm. Copyright © 2014 Cengage Learning THE ECONOMICS OF DISCRIMINATION Discrimination occurs when the marketplace offers different opportunities to similar individuals who differ only by race, ethnic group, sex, age, or other personal characteristics. Copyright © 2014 Cengage Learning Measuring Labour Market DiscriminationDiscrimination is often measured by looking at the average wages of different groups.However simply observing differences in wages among broad groups—white and black, men and women—says little about the prevalence of discrimination.
  • 74. Copyright © 2014 Cengage Learning Measuring Labour Market DiscriminationEven in a labour market free of discrimination, different people have different wages. People differ in the amount of human capital they have and in the kinds of work they are willing and able to do. Differences in average wages among groups in part reflect differences in human capital and job characteristics so by themselves they don’t say anything about how much labour discrimination. Copyright © 2014 Cengage Learning Discrimination by EmployersFirms that do not discriminate will: Have lower labour costs when they hire the employees
  • 75. discriminated against. Tend to replace firms that discriminate. Be more profitable than those firms that do discriminate.Competitive markets tend to limit the impact of discrimination on wages. Copyright © 2014 Cengage Learning Discrimination by Customers and GovernmentsAlthough the profit motive is a strong force acting to eliminate discriminatory wage differentials, there are limits to its corrective abilities. Customer preferences Government policies Copyright © 2014 Cengage Learning
  • 76. Discrimination by Customers and GovernmentsCustomer preferences: If customers have discriminatory preferences, a competitive market is consistent with a discriminatory wage differential. This will happen when customers are willing to pay to maintain the discriminatory practice. Copyright © 2014 Cengage Learning Discrimination by Customers and GovernmentsGovernment policies: When the government mandates discriminatory practices or requires firms to discriminate, this may also lead to discriminatory wage differentials. Copyright © 2014 Cengage Learning
  • 77. Becker’s Employer Taste Model People may have a ‘taste’ for only working with certain groups of people. Those outside this accepted group may end up being disadvantaged as a result. Copyright © 2014 Cengage Learning OTHER FACTORS OF PRODUCTION: LAND AND CAPITAL Capital refers to the equipment and structures used to produce goods and services. The economy’s capital represents the accumulation of goods produced in the past that are being used in the present to produce new goods and services. Copyright © 2014 Cengage Learning OTHER FACTORS OF PRODUCTION: LAND AND
  • 78. CAPITALPrices of Land and Capital. The purchase price is what a person pays to own a factor of production indefinitely. The rental price is what a person pays to use a factor of production for a limited period of time.The rental price of land and the rental price of capital are determined by supply and demand. The firm increases the quantity hired until the value of the factor’s marginal product equals the factor’s price. Copyright © 2014 Cengage Learning Figure 10 The Markets for Land and Capital
  • 80. Rental Price of Capital (a) The Market for Land (b) The Market for Capital Copyright©2014 Cengage Demand Supply Demand Supply Q P P Q
  • 81. Copyright © 2014 Cengage Learning Equilibrium in the Markets for Land and CapitalEach factor’s rental price must equal the value of its marginal product. They each earn the value of their marginal contribution to the production process. Copyright © 2014 Cengage Learning Linkages among the Factors of ProductionFactors of production are used together. The marginal product of any one factor depends on the quantities of all factors that are available.A change in the supply of one factor alters the earnings of all the factors.A change in earnings of any factor can be found by analysing the impact of the event on the value of the marginal product of that factor.
  • 82. Copyright © 2014 Cengage Learning ECONOMIC RENT Economic rent is the amount a factor of production earns over and above its transfer earnings. Transfer earnings refers to the minimum payment required to keep a factor of production in its current use. If economic rent exists for any factor of production, the government could, in theory, tax a portion of that rent without affecting the employment of that factor in a particular use. Copyright © 2014 Cengage Learning Figure 11 Economic Rent
  • 83. Copyright©2014 Cengage Copyright © 2014 Cengage Learning Summary The three most important factors of production are labour, land, and capital. The demand for a factor, such as labour, is a derived demand that comes from firms that use the factors to produce goods and services. Competitive, profit-maximizing firms hire each factor up to the
  • 84. point at which the value of the marginal product of the factor equals its price. The supply of labour arises from individuals’ tradeoff between work and leisure. Copyright © 2014 Cengage Learning Summary An upward-sloping labour supply curve means that people respond to an increase in the wage by enjoying less leisure and working more hours. The price paid to each factor adjusts to balance the supply and demand for that factor. Because factor demand reflects the value of the marginal product of that factor, in equilibrium each factor is compensated according to its marginal contribution to the production of goods and services. Because factors of production are used together, the marginal product of any one factor depends on the quantities of all factors that are available.
  • 85. Copyright © 2014 Cengage Learning Summary As a result, a change in the supply of one factor alters the equilibrium earnings of all the factors. Workers earn different wages for many reasons. To some extent, wage differentials compensate workers for job attributes. Workers with more human capital get paid more than workers with less human capital. The return to accumulating human capital is high and has increased over the past decade. There is much variation in earnings that cannot be explained by things economists can measure. Copyright © 2014 Cengage Learning
  • 86. Summary The unexplained variation in earnings is largely attributable to natural ability, effort, and chance. Signalling could partly help explain why more highly educated workers earn higher wages. Wages are sometimes pushed above the equilibrium level because of minimum wage laws, unions, and efficiency wages. Some differences in earnings are attributable to discrimination on the basis of race, sex, or other factors. Copyright © 2014 Cengage Learning Summary When measuring the amount of discrimination, one must correct for differences in human capital and job characteristics. Competitive markets tend to limit the impact of discrimination on wages. Discrimination can persist in competitive markets if customers are willing to pay more to discriminatory firms,
  • 87. or if the government passes laws requiring firms to discriminate. The UK’s minimum wage – not so good after all? (words 1998) W S Siebert, Feb 2013 Introduction There has been a decline in labour market prospects for the most vulnerable groups since the minimum wage was introduced in the UK. There is not sufficient UK evidence yet to pin much of the blame for this on the minimum wage, but the international evidence points in that direction. Proposals for imposing a “living wage” by soft or hard coercion could also be damaging. Brief history The UK’s minimum wage began in April 1999, fulfilling a promise of Blair’s new Labour government. Blair was responding to popular demand, since the Conservative government in 1993 had ended the old system of minimum wages. Michael Forsyth, the Employment Minister at the time
  • 88. said: “The biggest source of poverty is not low pay; it is having no job. Wages councils destroy employment”. However, most people, then and now, believe that there is a moral basis for a minimum wage, and the coalition government has not moved close to changing it. The national minimum wage (NMW) system has some interesting features. Firstly, it is set in a technocratic way by experts who rely on research. Although the Low Pay Commission has both TUC and CBI members, it also has academic members, and an independent chair. Hence, a careful sifting of the evidence on how the NMW bears on business – including business in the regions plays a large part in the debate. As such, changes in the NMW have responded closely to changes in the health of the economy. The biggest exception to this was in 2001 when the thrusting Stephen Byers saw electoral advantage in pushing the youth rate up considerably prior to the May 2001 election. The important point here is that the NMW is set explicitly to weigh as little on unemployment as possible. Secondly, the minimum wage is “national”, with no regional differentiation. The Low Pay Commission’s terms of reference from the beginning excluded such differentiation. Hence, arguably, the level has always been too high for the north, and too low for the London area. The NMW does, however, have
  • 89. several age categories, with a youth sub-minimum, and an even lower apprentice sub-minimum. Thus, it has been sensibly conceded that young workers and apprentices are less productive. Again, we see an effort to mute the unemployment consequences of the minimum. Despite this, the UK labour market is performing poorly for unskilled workers, as shown in Table 1, and the question must arise about the NMW’s role in this. We see that the 16-24 group’s unemployment rate has almost doubled to 24.7 per cent over the period since 1999. In addition, as the lower panel shows, their unemployment duration has worsened, with 28.2 per cent unemployed for over one year. In fact, as can be seen, the UK’s youth labour market is now putting in as bad a performance as France, long a youth unemployment blackspot Employment effects UK evidence. The minimum wage has been raised considerably over the period since 1999. Hence, it makes a lot of difference to unskilled workers’ earnings, and one would expect unemployment consequences unless counter-balanced by strong growth. The impact of the minimum wage can be seen in Figure 1. The 2010 distribution has had its lower tail cut off compared with the 1997. In fact, the NMW has increased by 72 per cent since 1999, considerably more than the 50% of the average worker’s wage.
  • 90. What effect has this had on job opportunities for the unskilled? There are inherent statistical difficulties of identifying the impacts of a policy that covers the whole of the UK. One way to judge this issue is to examine regional variation, since the NMW has more “bite” in poor than rich areas as shown in Figure 2, which compares the hypothetical effect in a district such as Cambridge with one such as Liverpool. Assume that productivity and the demand for labour is lower in Liverpool. The NMW requirement would move unskilled employment from point d (dictated by the level of welfare benefits) to point c (the demand for labour at the minimum wage). Meanwhile, employment in Cambridge would be barely affected. The first person to conduct this type of study was Mark Stewart (2002), who used data for changes in wages and employment in about 150 UK regions for the first year of the NMW. He found no adverse effect, but with only one data point per region he could not allow for region-specific trends or long-run effects. His work has recently been updated (Dolton et al 2013, 26) using all data including the recession, and concludes the regions with more NMW bite indeed have lower employment other things equal: The elasticity is around 0.1 implying that a 10 percent increase in the bite of the minimum wage [relative to the area
  • 91. wage]would lead to a fall of 1 per cent of the employment rate”. An alternative approach is to compare workers who have their wages raised by the NMW with workers paid just above that level (say, up to 10 per cent above the minimum). These workers should have similar skills, and welfare benefit options. This method was also pioneered for the UK by Stewart (2004). He again found no adverse NMW employment effects, but was only looking at one year of data. In fact, the latest work using this approach by Dickens and Riley (2012), using data up to 2010, does find unskilled workers are hit harder. In particular, this research finds that the probability of remaining in job (employment retention) is reduced by about three percentage points by the NMW for part- time women, the group who are most affected by the NMW (10% compared to about 2-3% for full-timers). This result is important because a 3 point reduction is large when measured against an average retention rate (i.e. probability of remaining in employment for one year) of around 70 per cent. So, the UK employment picture for the most vulnerable has deteriorated with the NMW. However, there is not enough data to draw firm conclusions as to the cause as yet. What does the international evidence suggest?
  • 92. International evidence. Studying a panel of countries or states (for example in the USA) offers a better way of analysing minimum wages since there is more variation in the minimum. An important study of long-run effects is that by Baker at al (1999) for nine Canadian provinces for 1975-93. He found that a 10 per cent increase in the minimum wage reduces teenage employment by 2.5 per cent and that it takes about six years for the full result. There have been other international panel studies, all finding adverse effects. Neumark and Wascher’s (2004) analysis of 17 OECD countries for the period 1975-2000 finds that a 10 per cent increase in the minimum wage leads to a two per cent reduction in the employment rate for younger people (15-24). Recent work by Dolton and Bondiabene (2012) confirms these estimates and also suggests that the impact of minimum wages tends to double during a recession. Finally, the work by Addison and Ozturk (2012) concentrates on employment outcomes for adult women. They estimate that a 10 per cent increase in the minimum wage will reduce employment by 1.5 per cent. In sum, while the UK evidence is thinner due to statistical
  • 93. problems, the research overall points to the minimum wage reducing employment as conventional economic theory predicts. In other words, the minimum wage undermines employment for the least productive whilst raising wages for others. The research also suggests that the workers who benefit are the better-off. Thus, where there is high unemployment there is heightened competition for jobs, with the better connected workers – teenagers from better educated families rather than the poor finding them (see Ahn et al. 2011). Morality and new proposals for a “living wage” Going beyond the NMW, the Joseph Rowntree Foundation and others are calling for a “living wage” of £7.45 an hour. We are told that “the moral pressures are winning out over the economic pressures” (Hirsh 2012). Yet what moral virtue is there in a policy that causes the loss of jobs for low-wage, low- skill workers or which causes the lengthening of unemployment duration? Countries with high minimum wages and/or high social costs - such as France - have high long-term unemployment (where nearly half the unemployed have been jobless for longer than a year). The living wage would be tied only to living costs and median incomes and not to labour market conditions. As we have seen, the unemployment effect of the UK minimum wage has been
  • 94. reduced because of the pragmatism of those setting the rate. The imposition of the living wage – regardless of labour market conditions - would be a recipe for increased long-term unemployment. A functioning market would have much lower wages in Liverpool than in Cambridge, which would attract business, and relieve poor unemployed people. If the market were allowed to work – which would require lower benefits as well as lower wages since benefits form a floor under wages - then businesses would move north. Of course, it is difficult to take on the benefit system, but even tax breaks for businesses in development areas would be better than a living wage. The living wage would push wages up for favoured workers in large firms and in government, but would do nothing for those trapped within our dysfunctional “permanent” welfare system.In fact, there are other policies, such as better schooling (and reduced teacher union power), reduced regulation and taxes, that could enable unskilled workers to become independent and earn their their own “living wages”. References Addison John and Orgul Ozturk (2012). “Minimum Wages, Labor Market Institutions, and Female Employment: A Cross- Country Analysis”, Industrial and Labor Relations Review, 65:
  • 95. 779-809. Ahn, Tom, Peter Arcidiacono and Walter Wessels (2011). “The Distributional Impacts of Minimum Wage Increases when both Labor Supply and Labor Demand are Endogenous”, 29: 12-23. Baker, Michael, Dwayne Benjamin and Shuchita Stanger (1999). “The Highs and Lows of the Minimum Wage Effect: A Time- Series Cross-Section Study of the Canadian Law”, Journal of Labor Economics, 17: 318-50. Commission (2012). National Minimum Wage - Report 2012, Cm 8302, London: Low Pay Commission. Dickens, Richard, Rebecca Riley and David Wilkinson (2012), “Re-examining the Impact of the National Minimum Wage on Earnings, Employment and Hours: the Importance of Recession and Firm Size”, Research Report Commissioned for the 2012 Report, http://www.lowpay.gov.uk/lowpay/research/pdf/ Dolton, Peter and Chiara Bondibene (2012). “The International Experience of Minimum Wages in an Economic Downturn”, Economic Policy, 27: 99-142. Dolton, Peter, Chiara Bondibene and Michael Stops, 2013. “Identifying the Employment Effect of Invoking and Changing the Minimum Wage: A Spatial Analysis of the UK”, unpublished working paper, University of Sussex. Hirsch, Donald (2012), “The Living Wage: Where Morality and Economics Meet”, Joseph Rowntree Foundation, www.jrf.org.uk/focus-issue/minimum-income-standards
  • 96. Stewart, Mark (2002), “Estimating the Impact of the Minimum Wage Using Geographic Wage Variation”, Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics, 64: 583-606. Stewart, Mark (2004), The impact of the introduction of the UK minimum wage on the employment probabilities of low wage workers. Journal of the European Economic Association, 2: 67– 97. Figure 1: Changes in the Earnings Distribution due to the NMW Source: Commission (2011), Figure 2.9 ( Supply D C ambridge wage a Welfare Labour hours
  • 98. Table 1: Adverse Changes in Employment for Unskilled Workers All, 16-65 No qualifications 16-24 France, 15-24 Unemployment rate (%) 1999 6.3 12.1 13.8 24.2 2011 8.1 17.0 24.7 22.1 Change 1999-2011 (% points) 1.8 7.9
  • 99. 10.9 -2.1 Unemployment duration (% of unemployed > 12 months) 1999 28.7 NA 15.3 France, total 40.3 2011 33.3 NA 28.2 41.4 Change 1999-2011 (% points) 4.6 NA 12.9 1.1 Sources: Commission (2012, Table 2.10), ONS (2012) and OECD (2000, 2012)
  • 100. 6 Intermediate Business Economics and the Macroeconomy UPDATED ESSAY NOTES W S Siebert, 28/9/15 The essay task is to choose ONE area of economic policy from the list below, regulated by a Singapore government authority as shown. Explain the relevant economics that underlies the area you choose. Summarise and evaluate the arguments for and against intervention by the authority. (2000 words essay) The areas are as follows, choose ONE: 1) Electricity supply and pricing – authority: Energy Market Authority (EMA) 2) Competition and merger regulation authority: Competition Commission of Singapore (CCS) 3) Environmental protection authority: Natural Environment Agency (NEA) 4) Wage regulation authority: National Wages Council (NWC) (we will be working on wage regulation for this essay, so u can ignore the first three.)
  • 101. Deadline: 4th November 2015; length: text 2000 words (references, tables, graphs and appendices are excluded from the count); at least one table and one graph must be included in your essay, and at least 6 references Basic Structure A structure that highlights the economic issues and solutions (and compromises) discussed in the module is required.Having chosen your area, you might build on · a situation that has been discussed in the lectures · a problem you have read about in a newspaper or heard about on the news · a discussion you find on one of the Singapore authorities’ websites But make sure it contains economic theory relevant to the area you have chosen, e.g.: Area Economic theories Sections in Mankiw-Taylor Electricity Natural monopoly, utility regulation Chap 6 (basic competition), chap14 (economies of scale, natural
  • 102. monopoly, e.g. slide 35) Competition Monopoly power, cartels, collusion Chap 6 (basic competition), chap 14 (monopoly and competition compared, e.g. slide 21), chap 16 (cartels) Environment Externalities, property rights, prisoner’s dilemma Chapters 10 (e.g., slide 10) and chap 11 (public goods, externalities) Wages Wage determination, minimum wages, welfare safety nets Chap 17 (labour markets, e.g. slides 38-9), chap 18 (inequality slides 36-7) Introduction: What problem are you analysing? Give the question or hypothesis that is to be your focus. Give a brief overview of the main issues involved. Typical questions or hypotheses in each of the four areas are as follows: · electricity and the EMA: the EMA has helped to ensure low cost and dependable electricity for Singapore · competition and the CCS: the Competition Commission successfully promotes competition, as shown by its decision, for example, to stop SITIC’s exclusive agreements · the environment and the NEA: the NEA helps improve air
  • 103. quality in Singapore which is difficult given cross-border haze problems · wages and the NWC: the NWC’s wage “guidelines” provide better employment opportunities than a minimum wage. Main body: First, I suggest starting with economic analysis. Explain the relevant economics behind the issues. Taking the four areas in turn we have problems of natural monopoly in the case of electricity supply and the EMA, collusion in the case of the CCS, the tragedy of the commons in the case of Indonesia’s fires, and labour market supply and demand and the problem of low wages in the case of the NWC. Start with a simple diagrammatic analysis if possible. Then, take up the facts and statistics. Explain the reasoning for the authority’s policies – go to the authority’s website, and discuss why and when it was set up. Discuss its history and achievements, and draw up a table if possible using statistics to demonstrate its achievements. Comparison with other countries is not necessary, but can be useful – the UK for example, has regulation of electricity, and also has a minimum wage. Conclusion: what have been the advantages and disadvantages of the authorities policies? Try and use specific examples, and
  • 104. relate to supply and demand analysis as taught in the module. Final word: keep it simple. Use your chosen authority’s website for the practical detail of what has happened in Singapore, and use Mankiw-Taylor for the supply and demand foundation. Tell a story about how Singapore’s government authorities help solve basic economic problems, using graphs and data.
  • 105. Requirements · Clear structure, with Introduction; Main body; Conclusions; References · Introduction sets out your questions · Main body: develop your arguments and analysis · Conclusions – provide a brief summary and discuss implications (if any) for business · References need to be complete Writing the essay · Stick to the word limit · You are not being judged on the elegance of your English, but your paragraphs must have a structure: · beginning, middle and end · clear leading sentence, and concluding sentence to each paragraph · It is good to discuss matters with others in preparing the essay, but write everything yourself
  • 106. · Leave yourself time to proofread before submitting Explaining the Economics · In your essay, you should show that you can understand and apply some of the economics we have covered in this module · Explain the theory that relates to the case you choose (see following slides) · You may use diagrams for your explanation (e.g. contrasting competition with monopoly, then showing possible welfare losses) · Use the economics to analyse different policy measures – i.e. refer back to the theory when discussing policies Plagiarism · Make sure you use your own words when writing the essay · All sources need to be correctly referenced · Do not copy and paste: this is the best way to avoid plagiarism · Use direct quotes only when absolutely necessary · Beware of collusion: working closely with a friend on a similar topic and writing very similar essays · Your essay will be checked for plagiarism · Consequences can be significant
  • 107. Summary of Advice · Choose an area quickly and collect information · Remember that to get a good mark you need to show that you can understand and apply the relevant economics · It is a short essay:– every word must be necessary · Make sure your essay is written in your own words all essays are checked for copying using Turnitin · Any questions? Ask now or email me 1