SlideShare a Scribd company logo
1 of 8
Download to read offline
THE ECONOMIC THEORY AND THE PORTUGUESE
                   MANUFACTURED INDUSTRY
                                 Vitor João Pereira Domingues Martinho

                             Unidade de I&D do Instituto Politécnico de Viseu
                                  Av. Cor. José Maria Vale de Andrade
                                           Campus Politécnico
                                            3504 - 510 Viseu
                                             (PORTUGAL)
                                    e-mail: vdmartinho@esav.ipv.pt


         ABSTRACT

          This work aims to test the Verdoorn Law, with the alternative specifications of (1)Kaldor (1966),
for the five Portuguese regions (NUTS II), from 1986 to 1994. It is intended to test, yet in this work, the
alternative interpretation of (2)Rowthorn (1975) about the Verdoorn's Law for the same regions and period.
The results of this study are about each one of the manufactured industries operating in the Portuguese
regions. The aim of this paper is, also, to present a further contribution to the analysis of absolute
convergence, associated with the neoclassical theory, of the manufactured industry productivity at regional
level and for the period from 1986 to 1994. This paper pretends, yet, to analyze the importance which the
natural advantages and local resources are in the manufacturing industry location, in relation with the
"spillovers" effects and industrial policies. To this, we estimate the Rybczynski equation matrix for the
various manufacturing industries in Portugal, at regional level (NUTS II) and for the period 1986 to 1994.

       Keywords: Verdoorn law; convergence theories; geographic concentration; panel data;
manufactured industries; Portuguese regions.

         1. INTRODUCTION

          Kaldor rediscovered the Verdoorn law in 1966 and since then this law has been tested in several
ways, using specifications, samples and different periods (3)(Martinho, 2011a). However, the conclusions
drawn differ, some of them rejecting the Law of Verdoorn and other supporting its validity. (4)Kaldor (1966,
1967) in his attempt to explain the causes of the low rate of growth in the UK, reconsidering and
empirically investigating Verdoorn's Law, found that there is a strong positive relationship between the
growth of labor productivity (p) and output (q), i.e. p = f (q). Or alternatively between employment growth
(e) and the growth of output, ie, e = f (q).
          Another interpretation of Verdoorn's Law, as an alternative to the Kaldor, is presented by
(5)Rowthorn (1975, 1979). Rowthorn argues that the most appropriate specification of Verdoorn's Law is
the ratio of growth of output (q) and the growth of labor productivity (p) with employment growth (e), i.e., q
= f (e) and p = f (e), respectively (as noted above, the exogenous variable in this case is employment). On
the other hand, Rowthorn believes that the empirical work of Kaldor (1966) for the period 1953-54 to 1963-
64 and the (6)Cripps and Tarling (1973) for the period 1951 to 1965 that confirm Kaldor's Law, not can be
accepted since they are based on small samples of countries, where extreme cases end up like Japan
have great influence on overall results.
          (7)Islam (1995) developed a model about the convergence issues, for panel data, based on the
(8)Solow model, (1956).
          Taking into account the work of (9)Kim (1999), we seek, aldo, to analyze the importance of the
natural advantages and local resources (specific factors of locations) have in explaining the geographic
concentration over time in the Portuguese regions, relatively effects "spillovers" and industrial policies (in
particular, the modernization and innovation that have allowed manufacturing in other countries take better
advantage of positive externalities). For this, we estimated the Rybczynski equation matrix for the different
manufacturing industries in the regions of Portugal, for the period 1986 to 1994. It should be noted that
while the model of inter-regional trade, the Heckscher-Ohlin-Vanek, presents a linear relationship between
net exports and inter-regional specific factors of locations, the Rybczynski theorem provides a linear
relationship between regional production and specific factors of locations. In principle, the residual part of
the estimation of Rybczynski, measured by the difference between the adjusted degree of explanation
(R2) and the unit presents a approximated estimate of the importance not only of the "spillovers” effects,
as considered by Kim (1999), but also of the industrial policies, because, industrial policies of
modernization and innovation are interconnected with the "spillover" effects. However, it must be some
caution with this interpretation, because, for example, although the growth of unexplained variation can be
attributed to the growing importance of externalities "Marshallians" or "spillovers" effects and industrial
policies, this conclusion may not be correct. Since the "spillovers" effects and industrial policies are
measured as a residual part, the growth in the residual can be caused, also, for example, by growth in the
randomness of the location of the products manufactured and the growing importance of external trade in
goods and factors (10)(Martinho, 2011b).

         2. ALTERNATIVE SPECIFICATIONS OF VERDOORN'S LAW

         The hypothesis of increasing returns to scale in industry was initially tested by Kaldor (1966)
using the following relations:

         pi  a  bqi , Verdoorn law (1)
         ei  c  dqi , Kaldor law (2)

where pi, qi and ei are the growth rates of labor productivity, output and employment in the industrial
sector in the economy i.

         On the other hand, the mathematical form of Rowthorn specification is as follows:

          pi  1   1ei , firts equation of Rowthorn (3)
         qi  2   2 ei , second equation of Rowthorn (4)
where  1  2 e  2  (1   1 ) , because             pi=qi-ei.   In   other   words,   qi  ei  1   1ei ,
qi  1  ei   1ei , so, qi  1  (1   1 )ei .

         Rowthorn estimated these equations for the same OECD countries considered by Kaldor (1966),
with the exception of Japan, and for the same period and found that  2 was not statistically different from
unity and therefore   1   was not statistically different from zero. This author thus confirmed the hypothesis
of constant returns to scale in manufacturing in the developed countries of the OECD. (11)Thirlwall (1980)
criticized these results, considering that the Rowthorn interpretation of Verdoorn's Law is static, since it
assumes that the Verdoorn coefficient depends solely on the partial elasticity of output with respect to
employment.

         3. CONVERGENCE MODEL

         The purpose of this part of the work is to analyze the absolute convergence of output per worker
(as a "proxy" of labor productivity), with the following equation Islam (1995), based on the Solow model,
1956):


          ln Pit  c  b ln Pi ,t 1   it                                                    (5)

      4. THE MODEL THAT ANALYZES THE IMPORTANCE OF NATURAL ADVANTAGES AND
LOCAL RESOURCES IN AGGLOMERATION

          According to Kim (1999), the Rybczynski theorem states that an increase in the supply of one
factor leads to an increased production of the good that uses this factor intensively and a reduction in the
production of other goods.
          Given these assumptions, the linear relationship between regional output and offers of regional
factors, may be the following:
                                                  Y  A1V ,
where Y (nx1) is a vector of output, A (nxm) is a matrix of factor intensities or matrix input Rybczynski and
V (mx1) is a vector of specific factors to locations.

          For the output we used the gross value added of different manufacturing industries, to the specific
factors of the locations used the labor, land and capital. For the labor we used the employees in
manufacturing industries considered (symbolized in the following equation by "Labor") and the capital,
because the lack of statistical data, it was considered, as a "proxy", the production in construction and
public works (the choice of this variable is related to several reasons including the fact that it represents a
part of the investment made during this period and symbolize the part of existing local resources,
particularly in terms of infrastructure). With regard to land, although this factor is often used as specific of
the locations, the amount of land is unlikely to serve as a significant specific factor of the locations.
Alternatively, in this work is used the production of various extractive sectors, such as a "proxy" for the
land. These sectors, include agriculture, forestry and fisheries (represented by "Agriculture") and
production of natural resources and energy (symbolized by "Energy"). The overall regression is then used
as follows:

ln Yit    1 ln Laborit   2 ln Agricultur eit   3 ln Energy it   4 ln Constructi onit           (6)

         In this context, it is expected that there is, above all, a positive relationship between the
production of each of the manufacturing industry located in a region and that region-specific factors
required for this industry, in particular, to emphasize the more noticeable cases, between food industry and
agriculture, among the textile industry and labor (given the characteristics of this industry), among the
industry of metal products and metal and mineral extraction and from the paper industry and forest.

         5 DATA ANALYSIS

          Considering the variables on the models presented previously and the availability of statistical
information, we used the following data disaggregated at regional level. Annual data for the period 1986 to
1994, corresponding to the five regions of mainland Portugal (NUTS II), and for the several manufactured
industries in those regions. The data are relative, also, to regional gross value added of agriculture,
fisheries and forestry, natural resources and energy and construction and public works. These data were
obtained from Eurostat (Eurostat Regio of Statistics 2000).

         6. EMPIRICAL EVIDENCE OF THE VERDOORN'S LAW

          The results in Table 1, obtained in the estimations carried out with the equations of Verdoorn,
Kaldor and Rowthorn for each of the manufacturing industries, enable us to present the conclusions
referred following.
          Manufacturing industries that have, respectively, higher increasing returns to scale are the
industry of transport equipment (5.525), the food industry (4.274), industrial minerals (3.906), the metal
industry (3.257), the several industry (2.222), the textile industry (1.770), the chemical industry (1.718) and
industry equipment and electrical goods (presents unacceptable values). The paper industry has
excessively high values. Note that, as expected, the transportation equipment industry and the food
industry have the best economies of scale (they are modernized industries) and the textile industry has the
lowest economies of scale (industry still very traditional, labor intensive, and in small units).
          Also in Table 1 presents the results of an estimation carried out with 9 manufacturing industries
disaggregated and together (with 405 observations). By analyzing these data it appears that were obtained
respectively for the coefficients of the four equations, the following elasticities: 0.608, 0.392, -0.275 and
0.725. Therefore, values that do not indicate very strong increasing returns to scale, as in previous
estimates, but are close to those obtained by Verdoorn and Kaldor.

Table 1: Analysis of economies of scale through the equation Verdoorn, Kaldor and Rowthorn, for each of
          the manufacturing industries and in the five NUTS II of Portugal, for the period 1986 to 1994
Metal Industry
                                                                    2
                  Constant       Coefficient       DW             R                G.L.           E.E. (1/(1-b))
Verdoorn          -4.019*        0.693*
pi  a  bqi
                                                   1.955          0.898            29
                  (-2.502)       (9.915)
Kaldor            4.019*         0.307*
ei  c  dqi
                                                   1.955          0.788            29
                  (2.502)        (4.385)
Rowthorn1                                                                                         3.257
                  -12.019        0.357
pi  1   1ei
                                                   1.798          0.730            29
                  (-0.549)       (1.284)
Rowthorn2         -12.019        1.357*
qi  2   2 ei                                   1.798          0.751            29
                  (-0.549)       (4.879)
Mineral Industry
                                                                    2
                  Constant       Coefficient       DW             R                G.L.           E.E. (1/(1-b))
                  -0.056*        0.744*
Verdoorn                                           1.978          0.352            38
                  (-4.296)       (4.545)
                  0.056*         0.256
Kaldor                                             1.978          0.061            38
                  (4.296)        (1.566)
                                                                                                  3.906
                  -0.023         -0.898*
Rowthorn1                                          2.352          0.704            38
                  (-0.685)       (-9.503)
                  -0.023         0.102
Rowthorn2                                          2.352          0.030            38
                  (-0.685)       (1.075)
Chemical Industry
                                                                    2
                  Constant       Coefficient       DW             R                G.L.           E.E. (1/(1-b))
                  0.002          0.418*
Verdoorn                                           1.825          0.554            34             1.718
                  (0.127)        (6.502)
-0.002     0.582*
Kaldor                                   1.825   0.707   34
                (-0.127)   (9.052)
                9.413*     0.109
Rowthorn1                                1.857   0.235   33
                (9.884)    (0.999)
                9.413*     1.109*
Rowthorn2                                1.857   0.868   33
                (9.884)    (10.182)
Electrical Industry
                                                  2
                Constant   Coefficient   DW      R       G.L.   E.E. (1/(1-b))
                0.004      -0.126
Verdoorn                                 1.762   0.128   32
                (0.208)    (-1.274)
                -0.004     1.126*
Kaldor                                   1.762   0.796   32
                (-0.208)   (11.418)
                                                                ---
                0.019      -0.287*
Rowthorn1                                1.659   0.452   32
                (1.379)    (-4.593)
                0.019      0.713*
Rowthorn2                                1.659   0.795   32
                (1.379)    (11.404)
Transport Industry
                                                  2
                Constant   Coefficient   DW      R       G.L.   E.E. (1/(1-b))
                -0.055*    0.819*
Verdoorn                                 2.006   0.456   38
                (-2.595)   (5.644)
                0.055*     0.181
Kaldor                                   2.006   0.040   38
                (2.595)    (1.251)
                                                                5.525
                -0.001     -0.628*
Rowthorn1                                2.120   0.436   32
                (-0.029)   (-3.938)
                -0.001     0.372*
Rowthorn2                                2.120   0.156   32
                (-0.029)   (2.336)
Food Industry
                                                  2
                Constant   Coefficient   DW      R       G.L.   E.E. (1/(1-b))
                0.006      0.766*
Verdoorn                                 2.191   0.526   38
                (0.692)    (6.497)
                -0.006     0.234**
Kaldor                                   2.191   0.094   38
                (-0.692)   (1.984)
                                                                4.274
                0.048*     -0.679*
Rowthorn1                                1.704   0.324   38
                (2.591)    (-4.266)
                0.048*     0.321*
Rowthorn2                                1.704   0.097   38
                (2.591)    (2.018)
Textile Industry
                                                  2
                Constant   Coefficient   DW      R       G.L.   E.E. (1/(1-b))
                -0.008     0.435*
Verdoorn                                 2.117   0.271   34
                (-0.466)   (3.557)
                0.008      0.565*
Kaldor                                   2.117   0.386   34
                (0.466)    (4.626)
                                                                1.770
                0.002      -0.303*
Rowthorn1                                1.937   0.136   34
                (0.064)    (-2.311)
                0.002      0.697*
Rowthorn2                                1.937   0.454   34
                (0.064)    (5.318)
Paper Industry
                                                  2
                Constant   Coefficient   DW      R       G.L.   E.E. (1/(1-b))
                -0.062*    1.114*
Verdoorn                                 1.837   0.796   38
                (-3.981)   (12.172)
                0.062*     -0.114
Kaldor                                   1.837   0.039   38
                (3.981)    (-1.249)
                                                                
                0.028      -1.053*
Rowthorn1                                1.637   0.310   38
                (1.377)    (-4.134)
                0.028      -0.053
Rowthorn2                                1.637   0.001   38
                (1.377)    (-0.208)
Several Industry
                                                  2
                Constant   Coefficient   DW      R       G.L.   E.E. (1/(1-b))
                -1.212     0.550*
Verdoorn                                 2.185   0.529   37
                (-0.756)   (8.168)
                1.212      0.450*
Kaldor                                   2.185   0.983   37     2.222
                (0.756)    (6.693)
                8.483*     0.069
Rowthorn1                                2.034   0.175   37
                (24.757)   (1.878)
8.483*         1.069*
 Rowthorn2                                      2.034          0.975           37
                 (24.757)       (29.070)
 9 Manufactured Industry Together
                                                                 2
                 Constant       Coefficient     DW             R               G.L.           E.E. (1/(1-b))
                 -0.030*        0.608*
 Verdoorn                                       1.831          0.516           342
                 (-6.413)       (19.101)
                 0.030*         0.392*
 Kaldor                                         1.831          0.308           342
                 (6.413)        (12.335)
                                                                                              2.551
                 -0.003         -0.275*
 Rowthorn1                                      1.968          0.053           342
                 (-0.257)       (-4.377)
                 -0.003         0.725*
 Rowthorn2                                      1.968          0.280           342
                 (-0.257)       (11.526)
 Note: * Coefficient statistically significant at 5%, ** Coefficient statistically significant at 10%, GL,
 Degrees of freedom; EE, Economies of scale.


           7. EMPIRICAL EVIDENCE OF ABSOLUTE CONVERGENCE, PANEL DATA

         Table 2 presents the results for the absolute convergence of output per worker, in the estimations
 obtained for each of the manufactured industry of NUTS II, from 1986 to 1994 (12)(Martinho, 2011c).
         The convergence results obtained are statistically satisfactory for all manufacturing industries of
NUTS II.

  Table 2: Analysis of convergence in productivity for each of the manufacturing industries at the five NUTS
                                 II of Portugal, for the period 1986 to 1994
 Metals industry
 Method       Const.    D1        D2        D3        D4        D5        Coef.     T.C.     DW      R2      G.L.
                                                                          -0.024
              0.190
 Pooling                                                                  (-        -0.024   1.646   0.002   30
              (0.190)
                                                                          0.241)
                                                                          -
                        2.171**   2.143**   2.161**   2.752**             0.239**
 LSDV                                                           ---                 -0.273   1.759   0.198   27
                        (1.769)   (1.753)   (1.733)   (1.988)             (-
                                                                          1.869)
                                                                          -0.046
              0.407
 GLS                                                                      (-        -0.047   1.650   0.007   30
              (0.394)
                                                                          0.445)
 MInerals industry
 Method       Const.    D1        D2        D3        D4        D5        Coef.     T.C.     DW      R2      G.L.
                                                                          -0.085
              0.738
 Pooling                                                                  (-        -0.089   1.935   0.025   38
              (0.903)
                                                                          0.989)
                                                                          -0.208*
                        1.884*    1.970*    2.004*    1.926*    1.731**
 LSDV                                                                     (-        -0.233   2.172   0.189   34
                        (2.051)   (2.112)   (2.104)   (2.042)   (1.930)
                                                                          2.129)
                                                                          -0.109
              0.967
 GLS                                                                      (-        -0.115   1.966   0.039   38
              (1.162)
                                                                          1.246)
 Chemical industry
 Method      Const.     D1        D2        D3        D4        D5        Coef.     T.C.     DW      R2      G.L.
                                                                          -
              2.312**                                                     0.225**
 Pooling                                                                            -0.255   2.017   0.104   34
              (1.992)                                                     (-
                                                                          1.984)
                                                                          -0.621*
                        6.104*    6.348*    6.381*    6.664*    6.254*
 LSDV                                                                     (-        -0.970   1.959   0.325   30
                        (3.750)   (3.778)   (3.774)   (3.778)   (3.777)
                                                                          3.769)
                                                                          -
              2.038**                                                     0.198**
 GLS                                                                                -0.221   2.034   0.089   34
              (1.836)                                                     (-
                                                                          1.826)
 Electric goods industry
 Method       Const. D1           D2        D3        D4        D5        Coef.     T.C.     DW      R2      G.L.
                                                                          -0.083
              0.781
 Pooling                                                                  (-        -0.087   1.403   0.016   38
              (0.789)
                                                                          0.784)
                                                                          -0.381*
                        3.634*    3.552*    3.673*    3.636*    3.429*
 LSDV                                                                     (-        -0.480   1.259   0.167   34
                        (2.363)   (2.360)   (2.362)   (2.376)   (2.324)
                                                                          2.355)
-0.025
              0.242
GLS                                                                        (-        -0.025    1.438     0.002     38
              (0.285)
                                                                           0.279)
Transport equipments industry
Method      Const. D1         D2             D3        D4        D5        Coef.     T.C.      DW        R2        G.L.
                                                                           -0.464*
              4.460*
Pooling                                                                    (-        -0.624    2.258     0.206     38
              (3.110)
                                                                           3.136)
                                                                           -0.871*
                        8.061*     8.526*    8.614*    8.696*    8.077*
LSDV                                                                       (-        -2.048    2.049     0.429     34
                        (4.948)    (5.007)   (4.986)   (4.998)   (4.961)
                                                                           5.014)
                                                                           -0.596*
              5.735*
GLS                                                                        (-        -0.906    2.159     0.276     38
              (3.780)
                                                                           3.807)
Food industry
Method      Const.      D1         D2        D3        D4        D5        Coef.     T.C.      DW        R2        G.L.
                                                                           -0.027
              0.314
Pooling                                                                    (-        -0.027    1.858     0.005     38
              (0.515)
                                                                           0.443)
                                                                           -0.274*
                        2.841*     2.777*    2.899*    2.617*    2.593*
LSDV                                                                       (-        -0.320    1.786     0.198     34
                        (2.555)    (2.525)   (2.508)   (2.471)   (2.470)
                                                                           2.469)
                                                                           -0.005
              0.090
GLS                                                                        (-        -0.005    1.851     0.001     38
              (0.166)
                                                                           0.085)
Textile industry
Method        Const.    D1         D2        D3        D4        D5        Coef.     T.C.      DW        R2        G.L.
                                                                           -0.462*
              4.276*
Pooling                                                                    (-        -0.620    1.836     0.388     34
              (4.639)
                                                                           4.645)
                                                                           -0.595*
                        5.556*     5.487*    5.506*    5.561*    5.350*
LSDV                                                                       (-        -0.904    1.816     0.431     30
                        (4.288)    (4.276)   (4.272)   (4.253)   (4.431)
                                                                           4.298)
                                                                           -0.347*
              3.212*
GLS                                                                        (-        -0.426    1.848     0.542     34
              (6.336)
                                                                           6.344)
Paper industry
Method       Const.     D1         D2        D3        D4        D5        Coef.     T.C.      DW        R2        G.L.
                                                                           -0.271*
              2.625*
Pooling                                                                    (-        -0.316    1.534     0.128     38
              (2.332)
                                                                           2.366)
                                                                           -0.382*
                        3.703*     3.847*    3.837*    3.684*    3.521*
LSDV                                                                       (-        -0.481    1.516     0.196     34
                        (2.803)    (2.840)   (2.813)   (2.812)   (2.782)
                                                                           2.852)
                                                                           -
              1.939**                                                      0.201**
GLS                                                                                  -0.224    1.556     0.089     38
              (1.888)                                                      (-
                                                                           1.924)
Several industry
Method       Const.     D1         D2        D3        D4        D5        Coef.     T.C.      DW        R2        G.L.
                                                                           -0.605*
              5.518*
Pooling                                                                    (-        -0.929    2.121     0.297     38
              (4.004)
                                                                           4.004)
                                                                           -0.847*
                        7.802*     7.719*    7.876*    7.548*    7.660*
LSDV                                                                       (-        -1.877    2.024     0.428     34
                        (5.036)    (5.022)   (5.033)   (5.023)   (5.018)
                                                                           5.032)
                                                                           -0.664*
              6.053*
GLS                                                                        (-        -1.091    2.081     0.328     38
              (4.308)
                                                                           4.309)
Note: Const. Constant; Coef., Coefficient, TC, annual rate of convergence; * Coefficient statistically significant at 5%, **
Coefficient statistically significant at 10%, GL, Degrees of freedom; LSDV, method of fixed effects with variables
dummies; D1 ... D5, five variables dummies corresponding to five different regions, GLS, random effects method.

          8. EMPIRICAL EVIDENCE OF GEOGRAPHIC CONCENTRATION

         In the results presented in the following table, there is a strong positive relationship between
gross value added and labor in particular in the industries of metals, chemicals, equipment and electrical
goods, textile and several products. On the other hand, there is an increased dependence on natural and
local resources in industries as the mineral products, equipment and electric goods, textile and several
products. We found that the location of manufacturing industry is yet mostly explained by specific factors of
locations and poorly explained by "spillovers" effects and industrial policies.
Table 3: Results of estimations for the years 1986-1994
          ln Yit    1 ln Laborit   2 ln Agricultur eit   3 ln Energy it   4 ln Constructi onit  
              IMT        IMI           IPQ          IEE           IET          IAL        ITE          IPA         IPD
              (2)        (1)           (1)          (1)           (1)          (2)        (1)          (1)         (2)
             10.010                                                           34.31(*)                            83.250(*)
              (0.810)                                                          (3.356)                             (5.412)
Dummy1                   18.753(*)     -13.467(*)   14.333(*)     9.183                   15.175(*)    17.850(*)
                         (5.442)       (-3.134)     (2.811)       (1.603)                 (3.652)      (3.162)
Dummy2                   19.334(*)     -12.679(*)   13.993(*)     10.084(**)              14.904(*)    17.532(*)
                         (5.733)       (-2.930)     (2.802)       (1.766)                 (3.597)      (3.100)
Dummy3                   19.324(*)     -13.134(*)   14.314(*)     10.155(**)              14.640(*)    18.586(*)
                         (5.634)       (-3.108)     (2.804)       (1.797)                 (3.534)      (3.313)
Dummy4                   18.619(*)     -11.256(*)   14.022(*)     9.384                   15.067(*)    15.001(*)
                         (5.655)       (-2.599)     (2.857)       (1.627)                 (3.647)      (2.654)
Dummy5                   17.860(*)     -11.060(*)   12.629(*)     7.604                   13.206(*)    13.696(*)
                         (5.629)       (-2.682)     (2.653)       (1.377)                 (3.344)      (2.574)
1            1.420(*)
              (4.965)
                         0.517(*)
                         (4.651)
                                       1.098(*)
                                       (8.056)
                                                    0.817(*)
                                                    (7.695)
                                                                  0.397(*)
                                                                  (2.455)
                                                                               0.378(*)
                                                                               (2.000)
                                                                                          0.809(*)
                                                                                          (5.962)
                                                                                                       -0.071
                                                                                                       (-0.230)
                                                                                                                   0.862(*)
                                                                                                                   (10.995)
2            0.844
              (1.353)
                         -0.358(*)
                         (-2.420)
                                       0.709(*)
                                       (2.628)
                                                    -0.085
                                                     (-0.480)
                                                                  -0.314
                                                                  (-0.955)
                                                                               -0.026
                                                                                (-
                                                                                          -0.484(**)
                                                                                          (-1.952)
                                                                                                       -0.171
                                                                                                        (-0.505)
                                                                                                                   -0.148
                                                                                                                   (-0.780)
                                                                               0.130)
3              0.431     -0.242(*)
                (1.468) (-3.422)
                                        0.120
                                        (0.721)
                                                     -0.084
                                                     (-0.876)
                                                                   0.147
                                                                   (0.844)
                                                                               -0.067
                                                                               (-0.706)
                                                                                         -0.229(**)
                                                                                         (-1.738)
                                                                                                      -0.165
                                                                                                      (-0.904)
                                                                                                                   -0.524(*)
                                                                                                                   (-5.289)

4              -1.459(*) 0.359(*)
                (-4.033) (2.629)
                                        0.260
                                        (1.185)
                                                     0.061
                                                     (0.318)
                                                                   0.433(*)
                                                                   (2.066)
                                                                               0.166
                                                                               (0.853)
                                                                                         0.529(*)
                                                                                         (2.702)
                                                                                                      0.427
                                                                                                      (1.596)
                                                                                                                   -0.085
                                                                                                                   (-0.461)
Sum of the 1.236          0.276         2.187        0.709         0.663       0.451     0.625        0.020        0.105
elasticities
  2
R adjusted 0.822          0.993         0.987        0.996         0.986       0.968     0.997        0.983        0.999
Residual        0.178     0.007         0.013        0.004         0.014       0.032     0.003        0.017        0.001
part
Durbin-         1.901     2.246         1.624        1.538         2.137       1.513     2.318        1.956        2.227
Watson
Hausman         (c)       115.873(b)(*) 26.702(b)(*) 34.002(b)(*) 9.710(b)(*) (c)        34.595(b)(*) 26.591(b)(*) 1.083(a)
test
For each of the industries, the first values correspond to the coefficients of each of the variables and values in
brackets represent t-statistic of each; (1) Estimation with variables "dummies"; (2) Estimation with random effects; (*)
coefficient statistically significant at 5% (**) Coefficient statistically significant at 10%; IMT, metals industries; IMI,
industrial mineral;, IPQ, the chemicals industries; IEE, equipment and electrical goods industries; EIT, transport
equipment industry; ITB, food industry; ITE, textiles industries; IPA, paper industry; IPD, manufacturing of various
products; (a) accepted the hypothesis of random effects; (b) reject the hypothesis of random effects; (c) Amount not
statistically acceptable.

          9. CONCLUSIONS

          At the level of estimates made for manufactured industries, it appears that those with,
respectively, higher dynamics are the transport equipment industry, food industry, minerals industrial,
metals industry, the several industries, the textile industry, chemical industry and equipment and electrical
goods industry. The paper industry has excessively high values.
          The signs of absolute convergence are different from one manufactured industries to another, but
there is a curious results for the equipment transport industry, because present strong evidence of
absolute convergence and we know that this industry is a dynamic sector.
          Of referring that the location of the Portuguese manufacturing industry is still mostly explained by
specific factors of locations and the industrial policies of modernization and innovation are not relevant,
especially those that have come from the European Union, what is more worrying.
          So, we can say that the strong increasing returns to scale in the same industries (like the
transport equipment industry) are not enough to avoid the convergence of this industries. On the other
hand, although, the strong increasing returns to scale in the some industries, the location of the
manufactured industries in Portugal is mostly explained by the specific factors of the locations.


          10. REFERENCES

1. N. Kaldor. Causes of the Slow Rate of Economics of the UK. An Inaugural Lecture. Cambridge:
Cambridge University Press, 1966.
2. R.E. Rowthorn. What Remains of Kaldor Laws? Economic Journal, 85, 10-19 (1975).
3. V.J.P.D. Martinho. The Verdoorn law in the Portuguese regions: a panel data analysis. MPRA Paper
32186, University Library of Munich, Germany (2011a).
4. N. Kaldor. Strategic factors in economic development. Cornell University, Itaca, 1967.
5. R.E. Rowthorn. A note on Verdoorn´s Law. Economic Journal, Vol. 89, pp: 131-133 (1979).
6. T.F. Cripps and R.J. Tarling. Growth in advanced capitalist economies: 1950-1970. University of
Cambridge, Department of Applied Economics, Occasional Paper 40, 1973.
7. N. Islam. Growth Empirics : A Panel Data Approach. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 110, 1127-1170
(1995).
8. R. Solow. A Contribution to the Theory of Economic Growth. Quarterly Journal of Economics (1956).
9. S. Kim. Regions, resources, and economic geography: Sources of U.S. regional comparative
advantage, 1880-1987. Regional Science and Urban Economics (29), 1-32 (1999).
10. V.J.P.D. Martinho. Geographic concentration in Portugal and regional specific factors. MPRA Paper
32317, University Library of Munich, Germany (2011b).
11. A.P. Thirlwall. Regional Problems are “Balance-of-Payments” Problems. Regional Studies, Vol. 14,
419-425 (1980).
12. V.J.P.D. Martinho. Sectoral convergence in output per worker between Portuguese regions. MPRA
Paper 32269, University Library of Munich, Germany (2011c).

More Related Content

What's hot

Entrepreneurial location strategic trend for region development - article ...
Entrepreneurial location    strategic trend for region development - article ...Entrepreneurial location    strategic trend for region development - article ...
Entrepreneurial location strategic trend for region development - article ...
NOELIO DANTASLÉ SPINOLA
 
Global Production Sharing: Patterns, Determinants and Macroeconomic implications
Global Production Sharing: Patterns, Determinants and Macroeconomic implicationsGlobal Production Sharing: Patterns, Determinants and Macroeconomic implications
Global Production Sharing: Patterns, Determinants and Macroeconomic implications
anucrawfordphd
 
Jobs and Growth in Finland: Industry-level Evidence from the 1990s
Jobs and Growth in Finland: Industry-level Evidence from the 1990sJobs and Growth in Finland: Industry-level Evidence from the 1990s
Jobs and Growth in Finland: Industry-level Evidence from the 1990s
Palkansaajien tutkimuslaitos
 
Labour reallocation over the business cycle during transition and post-transi...
Labour reallocation over the business cycle during transition and post-transi...Labour reallocation over the business cycle during transition and post-transi...
Labour reallocation over the business cycle during transition and post-transi...
GRAPE
 

What's hot (16)

Entrepreneurial location strategic trend for region development - article ...
Entrepreneurial location    strategic trend for region development - article ...Entrepreneurial location    strategic trend for region development - article ...
Entrepreneurial location strategic trend for region development - article ...
 
Sources of Job and Worker Flows: Evidence from a Panel of Regions
Sources of Job and Worker Flows: Evidence from a Panel of RegionsSources of Job and Worker Flows: Evidence from a Panel of Regions
Sources of Job and Worker Flows: Evidence from a Panel of Regions
 
Global Production Sharing: Patterns, Determinants and Macroeconomic implications
Global Production Sharing: Patterns, Determinants and Macroeconomic implicationsGlobal Production Sharing: Patterns, Determinants and Macroeconomic implications
Global Production Sharing: Patterns, Determinants and Macroeconomic implications
 
Jobs and Growth in Finland: Industry-level Evidence from the 1990s
Jobs and Growth in Finland: Industry-level Evidence from the 1990sJobs and Growth in Finland: Industry-level Evidence from the 1990s
Jobs and Growth in Finland: Industry-level Evidence from the 1990s
 
Does Labour Market Reorganization Reduce Unemployment?
Does Labour Market Reorganization Reduce Unemployment?Does Labour Market Reorganization Reduce Unemployment?
Does Labour Market Reorganization Reduce Unemployment?
 
The Micro-level Sources of Regional Productivity Growth in Finland
The Micro-level Sources of Regional Productivity Growth in FinlandThe Micro-level Sources of Regional Productivity Growth in Finland
The Micro-level Sources of Regional Productivity Growth in Finland
 
Presentation Manchester
Presentation ManchesterPresentation Manchester
Presentation Manchester
 
CASE Network Studies and Analyses 196 - An Approach to Forecasting Ukrainian ...
CASE Network Studies and Analyses 196 - An Approach to Forecasting Ukrainian ...CASE Network Studies and Analyses 196 - An Approach to Forecasting Ukrainian ...
CASE Network Studies and Analyses 196 - An Approach to Forecasting Ukrainian ...
 
Labour Market Flows in Poland - Did the Determinants Change?
Labour Market Flows in Poland - Did the Determinants Change?Labour Market Flows in Poland - Did the Determinants Change?
Labour Market Flows in Poland - Did the Determinants Change?
 
Labour reallocation over the business cycle during transition and post-transi...
Labour reallocation over the business cycle during transition and post-transi...Labour reallocation over the business cycle during transition and post-transi...
Labour reallocation over the business cycle during transition and post-transi...
 
Greece: Bed Linen – Market Report. Analysis and Forecast to 2025
Greece: Bed Linen – Market Report. Analysis and Forecast to 2025Greece: Bed Linen – Market Report. Analysis and Forecast to 2025
Greece: Bed Linen – Market Report. Analysis and Forecast to 2025
 
Av 1967-mar-4-abs
Av 1967-mar-4-absAv 1967-mar-4-abs
Av 1967-mar-4-abs
 
The importance of the Mix Methodology for Studying Offshore Energy sector
The importance of the Mix Methodology for Studying Offshore Energy sector The importance of the Mix Methodology for Studying Offshore Energy sector
The importance of the Mix Methodology for Studying Offshore Energy sector
 
Presentation coidine
Presentation coidinePresentation coidine
Presentation coidine
 
Can we really explain worker flows in transition economies?
Can we really explain worker flows in transition economies?Can we really explain worker flows in transition economies?
Can we really explain worker flows in transition economies?
 
Cyclical trend of labor reallocation: transition and structural change
Cyclical trend of labor reallocation:  transition and structural change Cyclical trend of labor reallocation:  transition and structural change
Cyclical trend of labor reallocation: transition and structural change
 

Viewers also liked

1informaticadibase 110602151357 Phpapp02
1informaticadibase 110602151357 Phpapp021informaticadibase 110602151357 Phpapp02
1informaticadibase 110602151357 Phpapp02
Formazioneenna Enna
 
Supermarket leads
Supermarket leadsSupermarket leads
Supermarket leads
bogo18
 
Upcoming Loans
Upcoming LoansUpcoming Loans
Upcoming Loans
bogo18
 
APPLICATION OF KEYNESIAN THEORY AND NEW ECONOMIC GEOGRAPHY IN PORTUGAL. DIFFE...
APPLICATION OF KEYNESIAN THEORY AND NEW ECONOMIC GEOGRAPHY IN PORTUGAL. DIFFE...APPLICATION OF KEYNESIAN THEORY AND NEW ECONOMIC GEOGRAPHY IN PORTUGAL. DIFFE...
APPLICATION OF KEYNESIAN THEORY AND NEW ECONOMIC GEOGRAPHY IN PORTUGAL. DIFFE...
Vítor João Pereira Domingues Martinho
 

Viewers also liked (6)

1informaticadibase 110602151357 Phpapp02
1informaticadibase 110602151357 Phpapp021informaticadibase 110602151357 Phpapp02
1informaticadibase 110602151357 Phpapp02
 
Supermarket leads
Supermarket leadsSupermarket leads
Supermarket leads
 
SPATIAL DATA ANALYSIS BASED ON THE CONVERGENCE THEORIES FOR PORTUGAL
SPATIAL DATA ANALYSIS BASED ON THE CONVERGENCE THEORIES FOR PORTUGALSPATIAL DATA ANALYSIS BASED ON THE CONVERGENCE THEORIES FOR PORTUGAL
SPATIAL DATA ANALYSIS BASED ON THE CONVERGENCE THEORIES FOR PORTUGAL
 
AN ALTERNATIVE USE OF THE VERDOORN LAW AT THE PORTUGUESE NUTS II LEVEL
AN ALTERNATIVE USE OF THE VERDOORN LAW AT THE PORTUGUESE NUTS II LEVELAN ALTERNATIVE USE OF THE VERDOORN LAW AT THE PORTUGUESE NUTS II LEVEL
AN ALTERNATIVE USE OF THE VERDOORN LAW AT THE PORTUGUESE NUTS II LEVEL
 
Upcoming Loans
Upcoming LoansUpcoming Loans
Upcoming Loans
 
APPLICATION OF KEYNESIAN THEORY AND NEW ECONOMIC GEOGRAPHY IN PORTUGAL. DIFFE...
APPLICATION OF KEYNESIAN THEORY AND NEW ECONOMIC GEOGRAPHY IN PORTUGAL. DIFFE...APPLICATION OF KEYNESIAN THEORY AND NEW ECONOMIC GEOGRAPHY IN PORTUGAL. DIFFE...
APPLICATION OF KEYNESIAN THEORY AND NEW ECONOMIC GEOGRAPHY IN PORTUGAL. DIFFE...
 

Similar to THE ECONOMIC THEORY AND THE PORTUGUESE MANUFACTURED INDUSTRY

SPATIAL DATA ANALYSIS BASED ON THE KEYNESIAN AND CONVERGENCE THEORIES FOR POR...
SPATIAL DATA ANALYSIS BASED ON THE KEYNESIAN AND CONVERGENCE THEORIES FOR POR...SPATIAL DATA ANALYSIS BASED ON THE KEYNESIAN AND CONVERGENCE THEORIES FOR POR...
SPATIAL DATA ANALYSIS BASED ON THE KEYNESIAN AND CONVERGENCE THEORIES FOR POR...
Vítor João Pereira Domingues Martinho
 
A MODEL FOR NET MIGRATION BETWEEN THE PORTUGUESE REGIONS. ANOTHER PERSPECTIVE
A MODEL FOR NET MIGRATION BETWEEN THE PORTUGUESE REGIONS. ANOTHER PERSPECTIVEA MODEL FOR NET MIGRATION BETWEEN THE PORTUGUESE REGIONS. ANOTHER PERSPECTIVE
A MODEL FOR NET MIGRATION BETWEEN THE PORTUGUESE REGIONS. ANOTHER PERSPECTIVE
Vítor João Pereira Domingues Martinho
 
A SPATIAL MODEL BASED ON THE ENDOGENOUS GROWTH THEORY FOR PORTUGAL. ANOTHER A...
A SPATIAL MODEL BASED ON THE ENDOGENOUS GROWTH THEORY FOR PORTUGAL. ANOTHER A...A SPATIAL MODEL BASED ON THE ENDOGENOUS GROWTH THEORY FOR PORTUGAL. ANOTHER A...
A SPATIAL MODEL BASED ON THE ENDOGENOUS GROWTH THEORY FOR PORTUGAL. ANOTHER A...
Vítor João Pereira Domingues Martinho
 

Similar to THE ECONOMIC THEORY AND THE PORTUGUESE MANUFACTURED INDUSTRY (20)

A MODEL OF THE KEYNESIAN THEORY FOR PORTUGAL
A MODEL OF THE KEYNESIAN THEORY FOR PORTUGALA MODEL OF THE KEYNESIAN THEORY FOR PORTUGAL
A MODEL OF THE KEYNESIAN THEORY FOR PORTUGAL
 
A MODEL OF THE KEYNESIAN THEORY FOR PORTUGAL.
A MODEL OF THE KEYNESIAN THEORY FOR PORTUGAL.A MODEL OF THE KEYNESIAN THEORY FOR PORTUGAL.
A MODEL OF THE KEYNESIAN THEORY FOR PORTUGAL.
 
WHAT THE KEYNESIAN THEORY SAID ABOUT PORTUGAL?
WHAT THE KEYNESIAN THEORY SAID ABOUT PORTUGAL?WHAT THE KEYNESIAN THEORY SAID ABOUT PORTUGAL?
WHAT THE KEYNESIAN THEORY SAID ABOUT PORTUGAL?
 
A MODEL BASED ON THE RYBCZYNSKI EQUATION FOR PORTUGAL. ANOTHER WAY
A MODEL BASED ON THE RYBCZYNSKI EQUATION FOR PORTUGAL. ANOTHER WAYA MODEL BASED ON THE RYBCZYNSKI EQUATION FOR PORTUGAL. ANOTHER WAY
A MODEL BASED ON THE RYBCZYNSKI EQUATION FOR PORTUGAL. ANOTHER WAY
 
A MODEL BASED ON THE RYBCZYNSKI EQUATION FOR PORTUGAL
A MODEL BASED ON THE RYBCZYNSKI EQUATION FOR PORTUGALA MODEL BASED ON THE RYBCZYNSKI EQUATION FOR PORTUGAL
A MODEL BASED ON THE RYBCZYNSKI EQUATION FOR PORTUGAL
 
A MODEL OF THE KEYNESIAN THEORY FOR PORTUGAL. ANOTHER APPROACH
A MODEL OF THE KEYNESIAN THEORY FOR PORTUGAL. ANOTHER APPROACHA MODEL OF THE KEYNESIAN THEORY FOR PORTUGAL. ANOTHER APPROACH
A MODEL OF THE KEYNESIAN THEORY FOR PORTUGAL. ANOTHER APPROACH
 
A MODEL FOR NET MIGRATION BETWEEN THE PORTUGUESE
A MODEL FOR NET MIGRATION BETWEEN THE PORTUGUESEA MODEL FOR NET MIGRATION BETWEEN THE PORTUGUESE
A MODEL FOR NET MIGRATION BETWEEN THE PORTUGUESE
 
SPATIAL DATA ANALYSIS BASED ON THE KEYNESIAN AND CONVERGENCE THEORIES FOR POR...
SPATIAL DATA ANALYSIS BASED ON THE KEYNESIAN AND CONVERGENCE THEORIES FOR POR...SPATIAL DATA ANALYSIS BASED ON THE KEYNESIAN AND CONVERGENCE THEORIES FOR POR...
SPATIAL DATA ANALYSIS BASED ON THE KEYNESIAN AND CONVERGENCE THEORIES FOR POR...
 
AGGLOMERATION AND INTERREGIONAL MOBILITY OF LABOR IN PORTUGAL
AGGLOMERATION AND INTERREGIONAL MOBILITY OF LABOR IN PORTUGALAGGLOMERATION AND INTERREGIONAL MOBILITY OF LABOR IN PORTUGAL
AGGLOMERATION AND INTERREGIONAL MOBILITY OF LABOR IN PORTUGAL
 
ANALYSIS OF NET MIGRATION BETWEEN THE PORTUGUESE REGIONS
ANALYSIS OF NET MIGRATION BETWEEN THE PORTUGUESE REGIONSANALYSIS OF NET MIGRATION BETWEEN THE PORTUGUESE REGIONS
ANALYSIS OF NET MIGRATION BETWEEN THE PORTUGUESE REGIONS
 
A MODEL FOR NET MIGRATION BETWEEN THE PORTUGUESE REGIONS. ANOTHER PERSPECTIVE
A MODEL FOR NET MIGRATION BETWEEN THE PORTUGUESE REGIONS. ANOTHER PERSPECTIVEA MODEL FOR NET MIGRATION BETWEEN THE PORTUGUESE REGIONS. ANOTHER PERSPECTIVE
A MODEL FOR NET MIGRATION BETWEEN THE PORTUGUESE REGIONS. ANOTHER PERSPECTIVE
 
Spatial Effects and Convergence Theory in the Portuguese
Spatial Effects and Convergence Theory in the PortugueseSpatial Effects and Convergence Theory in the Portuguese
Spatial Effects and Convergence Theory in the Portuguese
 
A SPATIAL MODEL BASED ON THE ENDOGENOUS GROWTH
A SPATIAL MODEL BASED ON THE ENDOGENOUS GROWTHA SPATIAL MODEL BASED ON THE ENDOGENOUS GROWTH
A SPATIAL MODEL BASED ON THE ENDOGENOUS GROWTH
 
Spatial Autocorrelation and Verdoorn Law in the Portuguese NUTs III
Spatial Autocorrelation and Verdoorn Law in the Portuguese NUTs IIISpatial Autocorrelation and Verdoorn Law in the Portuguese NUTs III
Spatial Autocorrelation and Verdoorn Law in the Portuguese NUTs III
 
SPATIAL DATA ANALYSIS BASED ON THE KEYNESIAN THEORY FOR PORTUGAL
SPATIAL DATA ANALYSIS BASED ON THE KEYNESIAN THEORY FOR PORTUGALSPATIAL DATA ANALYSIS BASED ON THE KEYNESIAN THEORY FOR PORTUGAL
SPATIAL DATA ANALYSIS BASED ON THE KEYNESIAN THEORY FOR PORTUGAL
 
A SPATIAL MODEL BASED ON THE ENDOGENOUS GROWTH THEORY FOR PORTUGAL. ANOTHER A...
A SPATIAL MODEL BASED ON THE ENDOGENOUS GROWTH THEORY FOR PORTUGAL. ANOTHER A...A SPATIAL MODEL BASED ON THE ENDOGENOUS GROWTH THEORY FOR PORTUGAL. ANOTHER A...
A SPATIAL MODEL BASED ON THE ENDOGENOUS GROWTH THEORY FOR PORTUGAL. ANOTHER A...
 
11.effect of land diversion from agriculture to industry in a dualistic economy
11.effect of land diversion from agriculture to industry in a dualistic economy11.effect of land diversion from agriculture to industry in a dualistic economy
11.effect of land diversion from agriculture to industry in a dualistic economy
 
A SPATIAL MODEL BASED ON THE ENDOGENOUS GROWTH
A SPATIAL MODEL BASED ON THE ENDOGENOUS GROWTHA SPATIAL MODEL BASED ON THE ENDOGENOUS GROWTH
A SPATIAL MODEL BASED ON THE ENDOGENOUS GROWTH
 
Fisher Theory and Stock Returns: An empirical investigation for industry stoc...
Fisher Theory and Stock Returns: An empirical investigation for industry stoc...Fisher Theory and Stock Returns: An empirical investigation for industry stoc...
Fisher Theory and Stock Returns: An empirical investigation for industry stoc...
 
NET MIGRATION AND CONVERGENCE IN PORTUGAL. AN
NET MIGRATION AND CONVERGENCE IN PORTUGAL. ANNET MIGRATION AND CONVERGENCE IN PORTUGAL. AN
NET MIGRATION AND CONVERGENCE IN PORTUGAL. AN
 

More from Vítor João Pereira Domingues Martinho

More from Vítor João Pereira Domingues Martinho (12)

A MODEL BASED ON THE ENDOGENOUS GROWTH THEORY FOR
A MODEL BASED ON THE ENDOGENOUS GROWTH THEORY FORA MODEL BASED ON THE ENDOGENOUS GROWTH THEORY FOR
A MODEL BASED ON THE ENDOGENOUS GROWTH THEORY FOR
 
A MODEL BASED ON THE NEOCLASSICAL THEORY FOR THE
A MODEL BASED ON THE NEOCLASSICAL THEORY FOR THEA MODEL BASED ON THE NEOCLASSICAL THEORY FOR THE
A MODEL BASED ON THE NEOCLASSICAL THEORY FOR THE
 
A MODEL BASED ON THE NEOCLASSICAL THEORY FOR
A MODEL BASED ON THE NEOCLASSICAL THEORY FORA MODEL BASED ON THE NEOCLASSICAL THEORY FOR
A MODEL BASED ON THE NEOCLASSICAL THEORY FOR
 
A SPATIAL MODEL OF THE KEYNESIAN THEORY FOR PORTUGAL
A SPATIAL MODEL OF THE KEYNESIAN THEORY FOR PORTUGALA SPATIAL MODEL OF THE KEYNESIAN THEORY FOR PORTUGAL
A SPATIAL MODEL OF THE KEYNESIAN THEORY FOR PORTUGAL
 
A NON LINEAR MODEL OF THE NEW ECONOMIC GEOGRAPHY
A NON LINEAR MODEL OF THE NEW ECONOMIC GEOGRAPHYA NON LINEAR MODEL OF THE NEW ECONOMIC GEOGRAPHY
A NON LINEAR MODEL OF THE NEW ECONOMIC GEOGRAPHY
 
A NON LINEAR MODEL OF THE NEW ECONOMIC GEOGRAPHY
A NON LINEAR MODEL OF THE NEW ECONOMIC GEOGRAPHYA NON LINEAR MODEL OF THE NEW ECONOMIC GEOGRAPHY
A NON LINEAR MODEL OF THE NEW ECONOMIC GEOGRAPHY
 
A LINEAR MODEL OF THE NEW ECONOMIC GEOGRAPHY FOR
A LINEAR MODEL OF THE NEW ECONOMIC GEOGRAPHY FORA LINEAR MODEL OF THE NEW ECONOMIC GEOGRAPHY FOR
A LINEAR MODEL OF THE NEW ECONOMIC GEOGRAPHY FOR
 
THE CONVERGENCE THEORIES AND THE GEOGRAPHIC
THE CONVERGENCE THEORIES AND THE GEOGRAPHICTHE CONVERGENCE THEORIES AND THE GEOGRAPHIC
THE CONVERGENCE THEORIES AND THE GEOGRAPHIC
 
THE CONVERGENCE THEORIES AND THE GEOGRAPHIC
THE CONVERGENCE THEORIES AND THE GEOGRAPHICTHE CONVERGENCE THEORIES AND THE GEOGRAPHIC
THE CONVERGENCE THEORIES AND THE GEOGRAPHIC
 
THE KEYNESIAN AND THE CONVERGENCE THEORIES IN THE
THE KEYNESIAN AND THE CONVERGENCE THEORIES IN THETHE KEYNESIAN AND THE CONVERGENCE THEORIES IN THE
THE KEYNESIAN AND THE CONVERGENCE THEORIES IN THE
 
THE KEYNESIAN AND THE CONVERGENCE THEORIES IN THE
THE KEYNESIAN AND THE CONVERGENCE THEORIES IN THETHE KEYNESIAN AND THE CONVERGENCE THEORIES IN THE
THE KEYNESIAN AND THE CONVERGENCE THEORIES IN THE
 
THE CONVERGENCE THEORIES AND THE MANUFACTURED
THE CONVERGENCE THEORIES AND THE MANUFACTUREDTHE CONVERGENCE THEORIES AND THE MANUFACTURED
THE CONVERGENCE THEORIES AND THE MANUFACTURED
 

Recently uploaded

Modular Monolith - a Practical Alternative to Microservices @ Devoxx UK 2024
Modular Monolith - a Practical Alternative to Microservices @ Devoxx UK 2024Modular Monolith - a Practical Alternative to Microservices @ Devoxx UK 2024
Modular Monolith - a Practical Alternative to Microservices @ Devoxx UK 2024
Victor Rentea
 
Architecting Cloud Native Applications
Architecting Cloud Native ApplicationsArchitecting Cloud Native Applications
Architecting Cloud Native Applications
WSO2
 
Why Teams call analytics are critical to your entire business
Why Teams call analytics are critical to your entire businessWhy Teams call analytics are critical to your entire business
Why Teams call analytics are critical to your entire business
panagenda
 
+971581248768>> SAFE AND ORIGINAL ABORTION PILLS FOR SALE IN DUBAI AND ABUDHA...
+971581248768>> SAFE AND ORIGINAL ABORTION PILLS FOR SALE IN DUBAI AND ABUDHA...+971581248768>> SAFE AND ORIGINAL ABORTION PILLS FOR SALE IN DUBAI AND ABUDHA...
+971581248768>> SAFE AND ORIGINAL ABORTION PILLS FOR SALE IN DUBAI AND ABUDHA...
?#DUbAI#??##{{(☎️+971_581248768%)**%*]'#abortion pills for sale in dubai@
 

Recently uploaded (20)

Web Form Automation for Bonterra Impact Management (fka Social Solutions Apri...
Web Form Automation for Bonterra Impact Management (fka Social Solutions Apri...Web Form Automation for Bonterra Impact Management (fka Social Solutions Apri...
Web Form Automation for Bonterra Impact Management (fka Social Solutions Apri...
 
How to Troubleshoot Apps for the Modern Connected Worker
How to Troubleshoot Apps for the Modern Connected WorkerHow to Troubleshoot Apps for the Modern Connected Worker
How to Troubleshoot Apps for the Modern Connected Worker
 
Corporate and higher education May webinar.pptx
Corporate and higher education May webinar.pptxCorporate and higher education May webinar.pptx
Corporate and higher education May webinar.pptx
 
CNIC Information System with Pakdata Cf In Pakistan
CNIC Information System with Pakdata Cf In PakistanCNIC Information System with Pakdata Cf In Pakistan
CNIC Information System with Pakdata Cf In Pakistan
 
Understanding the FAA Part 107 License ..
Understanding the FAA Part 107 License ..Understanding the FAA Part 107 License ..
Understanding the FAA Part 107 License ..
 
Modular Monolith - a Practical Alternative to Microservices @ Devoxx UK 2024
Modular Monolith - a Practical Alternative to Microservices @ Devoxx UK 2024Modular Monolith - a Practical Alternative to Microservices @ Devoxx UK 2024
Modular Monolith - a Practical Alternative to Microservices @ Devoxx UK 2024
 
Architecting Cloud Native Applications
Architecting Cloud Native ApplicationsArchitecting Cloud Native Applications
Architecting Cloud Native Applications
 
Artificial Intelligence Chap.5 : Uncertainty
Artificial Intelligence Chap.5 : UncertaintyArtificial Intelligence Chap.5 : Uncertainty
Artificial Intelligence Chap.5 : Uncertainty
 
"I see eyes in my soup": How Delivery Hero implemented the safety system for ...
"I see eyes in my soup": How Delivery Hero implemented the safety system for ..."I see eyes in my soup": How Delivery Hero implemented the safety system for ...
"I see eyes in my soup": How Delivery Hero implemented the safety system for ...
 
EMPOWERMENT TECHNOLOGY GRADE 11 QUARTER 2 REVIEWER
EMPOWERMENT TECHNOLOGY GRADE 11 QUARTER 2 REVIEWEREMPOWERMENT TECHNOLOGY GRADE 11 QUARTER 2 REVIEWER
EMPOWERMENT TECHNOLOGY GRADE 11 QUARTER 2 REVIEWER
 
Strategize a Smooth Tenant-to-tenant Migration and Copilot Takeoff
Strategize a Smooth Tenant-to-tenant Migration and Copilot TakeoffStrategize a Smooth Tenant-to-tenant Migration and Copilot Takeoff
Strategize a Smooth Tenant-to-tenant Migration and Copilot Takeoff
 
DBX First Quarter 2024 Investor Presentation
DBX First Quarter 2024 Investor PresentationDBX First Quarter 2024 Investor Presentation
DBX First Quarter 2024 Investor Presentation
 
Boost Fertility New Invention Ups Success Rates.pdf
Boost Fertility New Invention Ups Success Rates.pdfBoost Fertility New Invention Ups Success Rates.pdf
Boost Fertility New Invention Ups Success Rates.pdf
 
Apidays New York 2024 - The Good, the Bad and the Governed by David O'Neill, ...
Apidays New York 2024 - The Good, the Bad and the Governed by David O'Neill, ...Apidays New York 2024 - The Good, the Bad and the Governed by David O'Neill, ...
Apidays New York 2024 - The Good, the Bad and the Governed by David O'Neill, ...
 
Polkadot JAM Slides - Token2049 - By Dr. Gavin Wood
Polkadot JAM Slides - Token2049 - By Dr. Gavin WoodPolkadot JAM Slides - Token2049 - By Dr. Gavin Wood
Polkadot JAM Slides - Token2049 - By Dr. Gavin Wood
 
Why Teams call analytics are critical to your entire business
Why Teams call analytics are critical to your entire businessWhy Teams call analytics are critical to your entire business
Why Teams call analytics are critical to your entire business
 
+971581248768>> SAFE AND ORIGINAL ABORTION PILLS FOR SALE IN DUBAI AND ABUDHA...
+971581248768>> SAFE AND ORIGINAL ABORTION PILLS FOR SALE IN DUBAI AND ABUDHA...+971581248768>> SAFE AND ORIGINAL ABORTION PILLS FOR SALE IN DUBAI AND ABUDHA...
+971581248768>> SAFE AND ORIGINAL ABORTION PILLS FOR SALE IN DUBAI AND ABUDHA...
 
AWS Community Day CPH - Three problems of Terraform
AWS Community Day CPH - Three problems of TerraformAWS Community Day CPH - Three problems of Terraform
AWS Community Day CPH - Three problems of Terraform
 
FWD Group - Insurer Innovation Award 2024
FWD Group - Insurer Innovation Award 2024FWD Group - Insurer Innovation Award 2024
FWD Group - Insurer Innovation Award 2024
 
Repurposing LNG terminals for Hydrogen Ammonia: Feasibility and Cost Saving
Repurposing LNG terminals for Hydrogen Ammonia: Feasibility and Cost SavingRepurposing LNG terminals for Hydrogen Ammonia: Feasibility and Cost Saving
Repurposing LNG terminals for Hydrogen Ammonia: Feasibility and Cost Saving
 

THE ECONOMIC THEORY AND THE PORTUGUESE MANUFACTURED INDUSTRY

  • 1. THE ECONOMIC THEORY AND THE PORTUGUESE MANUFACTURED INDUSTRY Vitor João Pereira Domingues Martinho Unidade de I&D do Instituto Politécnico de Viseu Av. Cor. José Maria Vale de Andrade Campus Politécnico 3504 - 510 Viseu (PORTUGAL) e-mail: vdmartinho@esav.ipv.pt ABSTRACT This work aims to test the Verdoorn Law, with the alternative specifications of (1)Kaldor (1966), for the five Portuguese regions (NUTS II), from 1986 to 1994. It is intended to test, yet in this work, the alternative interpretation of (2)Rowthorn (1975) about the Verdoorn's Law for the same regions and period. The results of this study are about each one of the manufactured industries operating in the Portuguese regions. The aim of this paper is, also, to present a further contribution to the analysis of absolute convergence, associated with the neoclassical theory, of the manufactured industry productivity at regional level and for the period from 1986 to 1994. This paper pretends, yet, to analyze the importance which the natural advantages and local resources are in the manufacturing industry location, in relation with the "spillovers" effects and industrial policies. To this, we estimate the Rybczynski equation matrix for the various manufacturing industries in Portugal, at regional level (NUTS II) and for the period 1986 to 1994. Keywords: Verdoorn law; convergence theories; geographic concentration; panel data; manufactured industries; Portuguese regions. 1. INTRODUCTION Kaldor rediscovered the Verdoorn law in 1966 and since then this law has been tested in several ways, using specifications, samples and different periods (3)(Martinho, 2011a). However, the conclusions drawn differ, some of them rejecting the Law of Verdoorn and other supporting its validity. (4)Kaldor (1966, 1967) in his attempt to explain the causes of the low rate of growth in the UK, reconsidering and empirically investigating Verdoorn's Law, found that there is a strong positive relationship between the growth of labor productivity (p) and output (q), i.e. p = f (q). Or alternatively between employment growth (e) and the growth of output, ie, e = f (q). Another interpretation of Verdoorn's Law, as an alternative to the Kaldor, is presented by (5)Rowthorn (1975, 1979). Rowthorn argues that the most appropriate specification of Verdoorn's Law is the ratio of growth of output (q) and the growth of labor productivity (p) with employment growth (e), i.e., q = f (e) and p = f (e), respectively (as noted above, the exogenous variable in this case is employment). On the other hand, Rowthorn believes that the empirical work of Kaldor (1966) for the period 1953-54 to 1963- 64 and the (6)Cripps and Tarling (1973) for the period 1951 to 1965 that confirm Kaldor's Law, not can be accepted since they are based on small samples of countries, where extreme cases end up like Japan have great influence on overall results. (7)Islam (1995) developed a model about the convergence issues, for panel data, based on the (8)Solow model, (1956). Taking into account the work of (9)Kim (1999), we seek, aldo, to analyze the importance of the natural advantages and local resources (specific factors of locations) have in explaining the geographic concentration over time in the Portuguese regions, relatively effects "spillovers" and industrial policies (in particular, the modernization and innovation that have allowed manufacturing in other countries take better advantage of positive externalities). For this, we estimated the Rybczynski equation matrix for the different manufacturing industries in the regions of Portugal, for the period 1986 to 1994. It should be noted that while the model of inter-regional trade, the Heckscher-Ohlin-Vanek, presents a linear relationship between net exports and inter-regional specific factors of locations, the Rybczynski theorem provides a linear relationship between regional production and specific factors of locations. In principle, the residual part of the estimation of Rybczynski, measured by the difference between the adjusted degree of explanation (R2) and the unit presents a approximated estimate of the importance not only of the "spillovers” effects, as considered by Kim (1999), but also of the industrial policies, because, industrial policies of modernization and innovation are interconnected with the "spillover" effects. However, it must be some caution with this interpretation, because, for example, although the growth of unexplained variation can be attributed to the growing importance of externalities "Marshallians" or "spillovers" effects and industrial policies, this conclusion may not be correct. Since the "spillovers" effects and industrial policies are measured as a residual part, the growth in the residual can be caused, also, for example, by growth in the
  • 2. randomness of the location of the products manufactured and the growing importance of external trade in goods and factors (10)(Martinho, 2011b). 2. ALTERNATIVE SPECIFICATIONS OF VERDOORN'S LAW The hypothesis of increasing returns to scale in industry was initially tested by Kaldor (1966) using the following relations: pi  a  bqi , Verdoorn law (1) ei  c  dqi , Kaldor law (2) where pi, qi and ei are the growth rates of labor productivity, output and employment in the industrial sector in the economy i. On the other hand, the mathematical form of Rowthorn specification is as follows: pi  1   1ei , firts equation of Rowthorn (3) qi  2   2 ei , second equation of Rowthorn (4) where 1  2 e  2  (1   1 ) , because pi=qi-ei. In other words, qi  ei  1   1ei , qi  1  ei   1ei , so, qi  1  (1   1 )ei . Rowthorn estimated these equations for the same OECD countries considered by Kaldor (1966), with the exception of Japan, and for the same period and found that  2 was not statistically different from unity and therefore 1 was not statistically different from zero. This author thus confirmed the hypothesis of constant returns to scale in manufacturing in the developed countries of the OECD. (11)Thirlwall (1980) criticized these results, considering that the Rowthorn interpretation of Verdoorn's Law is static, since it assumes that the Verdoorn coefficient depends solely on the partial elasticity of output with respect to employment. 3. CONVERGENCE MODEL The purpose of this part of the work is to analyze the absolute convergence of output per worker (as a "proxy" of labor productivity), with the following equation Islam (1995), based on the Solow model, 1956):  ln Pit  c  b ln Pi ,t 1   it (5) 4. THE MODEL THAT ANALYZES THE IMPORTANCE OF NATURAL ADVANTAGES AND LOCAL RESOURCES IN AGGLOMERATION According to Kim (1999), the Rybczynski theorem states that an increase in the supply of one factor leads to an increased production of the good that uses this factor intensively and a reduction in the production of other goods. Given these assumptions, the linear relationship between regional output and offers of regional factors, may be the following: Y  A1V , where Y (nx1) is a vector of output, A (nxm) is a matrix of factor intensities or matrix input Rybczynski and V (mx1) is a vector of specific factors to locations. For the output we used the gross value added of different manufacturing industries, to the specific factors of the locations used the labor, land and capital. For the labor we used the employees in manufacturing industries considered (symbolized in the following equation by "Labor") and the capital, because the lack of statistical data, it was considered, as a "proxy", the production in construction and public works (the choice of this variable is related to several reasons including the fact that it represents a part of the investment made during this period and symbolize the part of existing local resources, particularly in terms of infrastructure). With regard to land, although this factor is often used as specific of the locations, the amount of land is unlikely to serve as a significant specific factor of the locations. Alternatively, in this work is used the production of various extractive sectors, such as a "proxy" for the land. These sectors, include agriculture, forestry and fisheries (represented by "Agriculture") and
  • 3. production of natural resources and energy (symbolized by "Energy"). The overall regression is then used as follows: ln Yit    1 ln Laborit   2 ln Agricultur eit   3 ln Energy it   4 ln Constructi onit   (6) In this context, it is expected that there is, above all, a positive relationship between the production of each of the manufacturing industry located in a region and that region-specific factors required for this industry, in particular, to emphasize the more noticeable cases, between food industry and agriculture, among the textile industry and labor (given the characteristics of this industry), among the industry of metal products and metal and mineral extraction and from the paper industry and forest. 5 DATA ANALYSIS Considering the variables on the models presented previously and the availability of statistical information, we used the following data disaggregated at regional level. Annual data for the period 1986 to 1994, corresponding to the five regions of mainland Portugal (NUTS II), and for the several manufactured industries in those regions. The data are relative, also, to regional gross value added of agriculture, fisheries and forestry, natural resources and energy and construction and public works. These data were obtained from Eurostat (Eurostat Regio of Statistics 2000). 6. EMPIRICAL EVIDENCE OF THE VERDOORN'S LAW The results in Table 1, obtained in the estimations carried out with the equations of Verdoorn, Kaldor and Rowthorn for each of the manufacturing industries, enable us to present the conclusions referred following. Manufacturing industries that have, respectively, higher increasing returns to scale are the industry of transport equipment (5.525), the food industry (4.274), industrial minerals (3.906), the metal industry (3.257), the several industry (2.222), the textile industry (1.770), the chemical industry (1.718) and industry equipment and electrical goods (presents unacceptable values). The paper industry has excessively high values. Note that, as expected, the transportation equipment industry and the food industry have the best economies of scale (they are modernized industries) and the textile industry has the lowest economies of scale (industry still very traditional, labor intensive, and in small units). Also in Table 1 presents the results of an estimation carried out with 9 manufacturing industries disaggregated and together (with 405 observations). By analyzing these data it appears that were obtained respectively for the coefficients of the four equations, the following elasticities: 0.608, 0.392, -0.275 and 0.725. Therefore, values that do not indicate very strong increasing returns to scale, as in previous estimates, but are close to those obtained by Verdoorn and Kaldor. Table 1: Analysis of economies of scale through the equation Verdoorn, Kaldor and Rowthorn, for each of the manufacturing industries and in the five NUTS II of Portugal, for the period 1986 to 1994 Metal Industry 2 Constant Coefficient DW R G.L. E.E. (1/(1-b)) Verdoorn -4.019* 0.693* pi  a  bqi 1.955 0.898 29 (-2.502) (9.915) Kaldor 4.019* 0.307* ei  c  dqi 1.955 0.788 29 (2.502) (4.385) Rowthorn1 3.257 -12.019 0.357 pi  1   1ei 1.798 0.730 29 (-0.549) (1.284) Rowthorn2 -12.019 1.357* qi  2   2 ei 1.798 0.751 29 (-0.549) (4.879) Mineral Industry 2 Constant Coefficient DW R G.L. E.E. (1/(1-b)) -0.056* 0.744* Verdoorn 1.978 0.352 38 (-4.296) (4.545) 0.056* 0.256 Kaldor 1.978 0.061 38 (4.296) (1.566) 3.906 -0.023 -0.898* Rowthorn1 2.352 0.704 38 (-0.685) (-9.503) -0.023 0.102 Rowthorn2 2.352 0.030 38 (-0.685) (1.075) Chemical Industry 2 Constant Coefficient DW R G.L. E.E. (1/(1-b)) 0.002 0.418* Verdoorn 1.825 0.554 34 1.718 (0.127) (6.502)
  • 4. -0.002 0.582* Kaldor 1.825 0.707 34 (-0.127) (9.052) 9.413* 0.109 Rowthorn1 1.857 0.235 33 (9.884) (0.999) 9.413* 1.109* Rowthorn2 1.857 0.868 33 (9.884) (10.182) Electrical Industry 2 Constant Coefficient DW R G.L. E.E. (1/(1-b)) 0.004 -0.126 Verdoorn 1.762 0.128 32 (0.208) (-1.274) -0.004 1.126* Kaldor 1.762 0.796 32 (-0.208) (11.418) --- 0.019 -0.287* Rowthorn1 1.659 0.452 32 (1.379) (-4.593) 0.019 0.713* Rowthorn2 1.659 0.795 32 (1.379) (11.404) Transport Industry 2 Constant Coefficient DW R G.L. E.E. (1/(1-b)) -0.055* 0.819* Verdoorn 2.006 0.456 38 (-2.595) (5.644) 0.055* 0.181 Kaldor 2.006 0.040 38 (2.595) (1.251) 5.525 -0.001 -0.628* Rowthorn1 2.120 0.436 32 (-0.029) (-3.938) -0.001 0.372* Rowthorn2 2.120 0.156 32 (-0.029) (2.336) Food Industry 2 Constant Coefficient DW R G.L. E.E. (1/(1-b)) 0.006 0.766* Verdoorn 2.191 0.526 38 (0.692) (6.497) -0.006 0.234** Kaldor 2.191 0.094 38 (-0.692) (1.984) 4.274 0.048* -0.679* Rowthorn1 1.704 0.324 38 (2.591) (-4.266) 0.048* 0.321* Rowthorn2 1.704 0.097 38 (2.591) (2.018) Textile Industry 2 Constant Coefficient DW R G.L. E.E. (1/(1-b)) -0.008 0.435* Verdoorn 2.117 0.271 34 (-0.466) (3.557) 0.008 0.565* Kaldor 2.117 0.386 34 (0.466) (4.626) 1.770 0.002 -0.303* Rowthorn1 1.937 0.136 34 (0.064) (-2.311) 0.002 0.697* Rowthorn2 1.937 0.454 34 (0.064) (5.318) Paper Industry 2 Constant Coefficient DW R G.L. E.E. (1/(1-b)) -0.062* 1.114* Verdoorn 1.837 0.796 38 (-3.981) (12.172) 0.062* -0.114 Kaldor 1.837 0.039 38 (3.981) (-1.249)  0.028 -1.053* Rowthorn1 1.637 0.310 38 (1.377) (-4.134) 0.028 -0.053 Rowthorn2 1.637 0.001 38 (1.377) (-0.208) Several Industry 2 Constant Coefficient DW R G.L. E.E. (1/(1-b)) -1.212 0.550* Verdoorn 2.185 0.529 37 (-0.756) (8.168) 1.212 0.450* Kaldor 2.185 0.983 37 2.222 (0.756) (6.693) 8.483* 0.069 Rowthorn1 2.034 0.175 37 (24.757) (1.878)
  • 5. 8.483* 1.069* Rowthorn2 2.034 0.975 37 (24.757) (29.070) 9 Manufactured Industry Together 2 Constant Coefficient DW R G.L. E.E. (1/(1-b)) -0.030* 0.608* Verdoorn 1.831 0.516 342 (-6.413) (19.101) 0.030* 0.392* Kaldor 1.831 0.308 342 (6.413) (12.335) 2.551 -0.003 -0.275* Rowthorn1 1.968 0.053 342 (-0.257) (-4.377) -0.003 0.725* Rowthorn2 1.968 0.280 342 (-0.257) (11.526) Note: * Coefficient statistically significant at 5%, ** Coefficient statistically significant at 10%, GL, Degrees of freedom; EE, Economies of scale. 7. EMPIRICAL EVIDENCE OF ABSOLUTE CONVERGENCE, PANEL DATA Table 2 presents the results for the absolute convergence of output per worker, in the estimations obtained for each of the manufactured industry of NUTS II, from 1986 to 1994 (12)(Martinho, 2011c). The convergence results obtained are statistically satisfactory for all manufacturing industries of NUTS II. Table 2: Analysis of convergence in productivity for each of the manufacturing industries at the five NUTS II of Portugal, for the period 1986 to 1994 Metals industry Method Const. D1 D2 D3 D4 D5 Coef. T.C. DW R2 G.L. -0.024 0.190 Pooling (- -0.024 1.646 0.002 30 (0.190) 0.241) - 2.171** 2.143** 2.161** 2.752** 0.239** LSDV --- -0.273 1.759 0.198 27 (1.769) (1.753) (1.733) (1.988) (- 1.869) -0.046 0.407 GLS (- -0.047 1.650 0.007 30 (0.394) 0.445) MInerals industry Method Const. D1 D2 D3 D4 D5 Coef. T.C. DW R2 G.L. -0.085 0.738 Pooling (- -0.089 1.935 0.025 38 (0.903) 0.989) -0.208* 1.884* 1.970* 2.004* 1.926* 1.731** LSDV (- -0.233 2.172 0.189 34 (2.051) (2.112) (2.104) (2.042) (1.930) 2.129) -0.109 0.967 GLS (- -0.115 1.966 0.039 38 (1.162) 1.246) Chemical industry Method Const. D1 D2 D3 D4 D5 Coef. T.C. DW R2 G.L. - 2.312** 0.225** Pooling -0.255 2.017 0.104 34 (1.992) (- 1.984) -0.621* 6.104* 6.348* 6.381* 6.664* 6.254* LSDV (- -0.970 1.959 0.325 30 (3.750) (3.778) (3.774) (3.778) (3.777) 3.769) - 2.038** 0.198** GLS -0.221 2.034 0.089 34 (1.836) (- 1.826) Electric goods industry Method Const. D1 D2 D3 D4 D5 Coef. T.C. DW R2 G.L. -0.083 0.781 Pooling (- -0.087 1.403 0.016 38 (0.789) 0.784) -0.381* 3.634* 3.552* 3.673* 3.636* 3.429* LSDV (- -0.480 1.259 0.167 34 (2.363) (2.360) (2.362) (2.376) (2.324) 2.355)
  • 6. -0.025 0.242 GLS (- -0.025 1.438 0.002 38 (0.285) 0.279) Transport equipments industry Method Const. D1 D2 D3 D4 D5 Coef. T.C. DW R2 G.L. -0.464* 4.460* Pooling (- -0.624 2.258 0.206 38 (3.110) 3.136) -0.871* 8.061* 8.526* 8.614* 8.696* 8.077* LSDV (- -2.048 2.049 0.429 34 (4.948) (5.007) (4.986) (4.998) (4.961) 5.014) -0.596* 5.735* GLS (- -0.906 2.159 0.276 38 (3.780) 3.807) Food industry Method Const. D1 D2 D3 D4 D5 Coef. T.C. DW R2 G.L. -0.027 0.314 Pooling (- -0.027 1.858 0.005 38 (0.515) 0.443) -0.274* 2.841* 2.777* 2.899* 2.617* 2.593* LSDV (- -0.320 1.786 0.198 34 (2.555) (2.525) (2.508) (2.471) (2.470) 2.469) -0.005 0.090 GLS (- -0.005 1.851 0.001 38 (0.166) 0.085) Textile industry Method Const. D1 D2 D3 D4 D5 Coef. T.C. DW R2 G.L. -0.462* 4.276* Pooling (- -0.620 1.836 0.388 34 (4.639) 4.645) -0.595* 5.556* 5.487* 5.506* 5.561* 5.350* LSDV (- -0.904 1.816 0.431 30 (4.288) (4.276) (4.272) (4.253) (4.431) 4.298) -0.347* 3.212* GLS (- -0.426 1.848 0.542 34 (6.336) 6.344) Paper industry Method Const. D1 D2 D3 D4 D5 Coef. T.C. DW R2 G.L. -0.271* 2.625* Pooling (- -0.316 1.534 0.128 38 (2.332) 2.366) -0.382* 3.703* 3.847* 3.837* 3.684* 3.521* LSDV (- -0.481 1.516 0.196 34 (2.803) (2.840) (2.813) (2.812) (2.782) 2.852) - 1.939** 0.201** GLS -0.224 1.556 0.089 38 (1.888) (- 1.924) Several industry Method Const. D1 D2 D3 D4 D5 Coef. T.C. DW R2 G.L. -0.605* 5.518* Pooling (- -0.929 2.121 0.297 38 (4.004) 4.004) -0.847* 7.802* 7.719* 7.876* 7.548* 7.660* LSDV (- -1.877 2.024 0.428 34 (5.036) (5.022) (5.033) (5.023) (5.018) 5.032) -0.664* 6.053* GLS (- -1.091 2.081 0.328 38 (4.308) 4.309) Note: Const. Constant; Coef., Coefficient, TC, annual rate of convergence; * Coefficient statistically significant at 5%, ** Coefficient statistically significant at 10%, GL, Degrees of freedom; LSDV, method of fixed effects with variables dummies; D1 ... D5, five variables dummies corresponding to five different regions, GLS, random effects method. 8. EMPIRICAL EVIDENCE OF GEOGRAPHIC CONCENTRATION In the results presented in the following table, there is a strong positive relationship between gross value added and labor in particular in the industries of metals, chemicals, equipment and electrical goods, textile and several products. On the other hand, there is an increased dependence on natural and local resources in industries as the mineral products, equipment and electric goods, textile and several products. We found that the location of manufacturing industry is yet mostly explained by specific factors of locations and poorly explained by "spillovers" effects and industrial policies.
  • 7. Table 3: Results of estimations for the years 1986-1994 ln Yit    1 ln Laborit   2 ln Agricultur eit   3 ln Energy it   4 ln Constructi onit   IMT IMI IPQ IEE IET IAL ITE IPA IPD (2) (1) (1) (1) (1) (2) (1) (1) (2)  10.010 34.31(*) 83.250(*) (0.810) (3.356) (5.412) Dummy1 18.753(*) -13.467(*) 14.333(*) 9.183 15.175(*) 17.850(*) (5.442) (-3.134) (2.811) (1.603) (3.652) (3.162) Dummy2 19.334(*) -12.679(*) 13.993(*) 10.084(**) 14.904(*) 17.532(*) (5.733) (-2.930) (2.802) (1.766) (3.597) (3.100) Dummy3 19.324(*) -13.134(*) 14.314(*) 10.155(**) 14.640(*) 18.586(*) (5.634) (-3.108) (2.804) (1.797) (3.534) (3.313) Dummy4 18.619(*) -11.256(*) 14.022(*) 9.384 15.067(*) 15.001(*) (5.655) (-2.599) (2.857) (1.627) (3.647) (2.654) Dummy5 17.860(*) -11.060(*) 12.629(*) 7.604 13.206(*) 13.696(*) (5.629) (-2.682) (2.653) (1.377) (3.344) (2.574) 1 1.420(*) (4.965) 0.517(*) (4.651) 1.098(*) (8.056) 0.817(*) (7.695) 0.397(*) (2.455) 0.378(*) (2.000) 0.809(*) (5.962) -0.071 (-0.230) 0.862(*) (10.995) 2 0.844 (1.353) -0.358(*) (-2.420) 0.709(*) (2.628) -0.085 (-0.480) -0.314 (-0.955) -0.026 (- -0.484(**) (-1.952) -0.171 (-0.505) -0.148 (-0.780) 0.130) 3 0.431 -0.242(*) (1.468) (-3.422) 0.120 (0.721) -0.084 (-0.876) 0.147 (0.844) -0.067 (-0.706) -0.229(**) (-1.738) -0.165 (-0.904) -0.524(*) (-5.289) 4 -1.459(*) 0.359(*) (-4.033) (2.629) 0.260 (1.185) 0.061 (0.318) 0.433(*) (2.066) 0.166 (0.853) 0.529(*) (2.702) 0.427 (1.596) -0.085 (-0.461) Sum of the 1.236 0.276 2.187 0.709 0.663 0.451 0.625 0.020 0.105 elasticities 2 R adjusted 0.822 0.993 0.987 0.996 0.986 0.968 0.997 0.983 0.999 Residual 0.178 0.007 0.013 0.004 0.014 0.032 0.003 0.017 0.001 part Durbin- 1.901 2.246 1.624 1.538 2.137 1.513 2.318 1.956 2.227 Watson Hausman (c) 115.873(b)(*) 26.702(b)(*) 34.002(b)(*) 9.710(b)(*) (c) 34.595(b)(*) 26.591(b)(*) 1.083(a) test For each of the industries, the first values correspond to the coefficients of each of the variables and values in brackets represent t-statistic of each; (1) Estimation with variables "dummies"; (2) Estimation with random effects; (*) coefficient statistically significant at 5% (**) Coefficient statistically significant at 10%; IMT, metals industries; IMI, industrial mineral;, IPQ, the chemicals industries; IEE, equipment and electrical goods industries; EIT, transport equipment industry; ITB, food industry; ITE, textiles industries; IPA, paper industry; IPD, manufacturing of various products; (a) accepted the hypothesis of random effects; (b) reject the hypothesis of random effects; (c) Amount not statistically acceptable. 9. CONCLUSIONS At the level of estimates made for manufactured industries, it appears that those with, respectively, higher dynamics are the transport equipment industry, food industry, minerals industrial, metals industry, the several industries, the textile industry, chemical industry and equipment and electrical goods industry. The paper industry has excessively high values. The signs of absolute convergence are different from one manufactured industries to another, but there is a curious results for the equipment transport industry, because present strong evidence of absolute convergence and we know that this industry is a dynamic sector. Of referring that the location of the Portuguese manufacturing industry is still mostly explained by specific factors of locations and the industrial policies of modernization and innovation are not relevant, especially those that have come from the European Union, what is more worrying. So, we can say that the strong increasing returns to scale in the same industries (like the transport equipment industry) are not enough to avoid the convergence of this industries. On the other hand, although, the strong increasing returns to scale in the some industries, the location of the manufactured industries in Portugal is mostly explained by the specific factors of the locations. 10. REFERENCES 1. N. Kaldor. Causes of the Slow Rate of Economics of the UK. An Inaugural Lecture. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1966. 2. R.E. Rowthorn. What Remains of Kaldor Laws? Economic Journal, 85, 10-19 (1975). 3. V.J.P.D. Martinho. The Verdoorn law in the Portuguese regions: a panel data analysis. MPRA Paper 32186, University Library of Munich, Germany (2011a). 4. N. Kaldor. Strategic factors in economic development. Cornell University, Itaca, 1967. 5. R.E. Rowthorn. A note on Verdoorn´s Law. Economic Journal, Vol. 89, pp: 131-133 (1979). 6. T.F. Cripps and R.J. Tarling. Growth in advanced capitalist economies: 1950-1970. University of Cambridge, Department of Applied Economics, Occasional Paper 40, 1973.
  • 8. 7. N. Islam. Growth Empirics : A Panel Data Approach. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 110, 1127-1170 (1995). 8. R. Solow. A Contribution to the Theory of Economic Growth. Quarterly Journal of Economics (1956). 9. S. Kim. Regions, resources, and economic geography: Sources of U.S. regional comparative advantage, 1880-1987. Regional Science and Urban Economics (29), 1-32 (1999). 10. V.J.P.D. Martinho. Geographic concentration in Portugal and regional specific factors. MPRA Paper 32317, University Library of Munich, Germany (2011b). 11. A.P. Thirlwall. Regional Problems are “Balance-of-Payments” Problems. Regional Studies, Vol. 14, 419-425 (1980). 12. V.J.P.D. Martinho. Sectoral convergence in output per worker between Portuguese regions. MPRA Paper 32269, University Library of Munich, Germany (2011c).