SlideShare a Scribd company logo
Applications of Rationalizability and Iterated Dominance
Econ 402
Yuhta Ishii
Introduction
Last lecture: provided basic definitions of
rationalizability/iterated dominance in an abstract setting.
Key take aways:
rationalizability and iterated dominance are equivalent.
Sometimes rationalizability leads to unique prediction.
Sometimes, it doesn’t.
Today: Apply rationalizability in some concrete examples.
Reading: Chapter 8
Cournot Duopoly
Suppose that two firms produce the same product.
Firm 1 and 2 simultaneously choose respective quantities: .
No cost of production (for simplicity).
Given these quantities, the total quantity is and the price is
determined by the demand curve:
Cournot Duopoly
Since costs are zero, each firm’s utility function is just given
by:
How do firms choose quantity in this market?
Benchmark
Before we solve the duopoly model, suppose we just have a
monopolist:
One monopolist who faces a demand curve:
Monopolist does not face any competition.
How does such a monopolist choose quantity?
The Monopoly Case
The optimal quantity, , here satisfies:
Notice the usual tradeoff in the monopoly problem:
Higher quantity entails higher amount sold, but lower price.
The monopolist at optimum equates marginal revenue to
marginal cost.
Back to Duopoly
Now suppose that there are two firms in the market.
How does the amount supplied change?
To solve for the supply decisions of each firm, we use iterated
dominance/rationalizability.
Iterated Dominance/Rationalizability
We first look for the set :
The pure strategies that are not strictly dominated in the
original game.
To compute this set, we first look at pure strategies that are best
responses to a pure strategy of the opponent firm.
Best Responses
Suppose that you are firm 1 and that firm 2 produces .
Then what is firm 2’s best response?
To solve this, we need to solve the following problem:
The optimal quantity then is given by:
Best Responses
Suppose that you are firm 1 and that firm 2 produces .
Then what is firm 2’s best response?
Similarly, if firm 1 produces , the firm 2’s best response is:
Best Responses in Cournot Duopoly
Higher the quantity of the opponent, the less I want to produce:
Intuitively, higher quantity of the opponent decreases the price
lower marginal revenue.
Best Responses in Cournot Duopoly
Now using the above, we know that the quantities are all in .
These pure strategies are all best responses to some pure
strategy of firm 2.
What about the quantities ?
We know that such pure strategies are not best responses
against any pure strategy.
But we do not know whether they are best responses against a
mixed belief.
We now show that they are not, and in fact they are strictly
dominated.
Strictly Dominated Strategies in Cournot Duopoly
Claim: For any is strictly dominated by .
To prove this, we need to show that for all ,
To see this, note that if we take the derivative of the left hand
side with respect to , we get:
Strictly Dominated Strategies in Cournot
But for all and any .
This means that the utility function
Is strictly decreasing in in the interval for all values of .
Strictly Dominated Strategies in Cournot
This then means that: whenever for all ,
This shows that any pure strategy strictly above 60 is strictly
dominated.
Combined with our first observation, we see that
Similarly, .
Iterated Dominance
But with iterated dominance, we shouldn’t stop there.
Now we are faced with a smaller game where each player
chooses strategies in .
We look for strictly dominated strategies in this reduced game.
Strictly Dominated Strategies in Reduced Game
We first determine what pure strategies are the best responses to
pure strategies in this reduced game:
Now notice that all strategies in [30,60] are best responses to
pure strategies.
So .
What about ?
Strictly Dominated Strategies in Reduced Game
Claim: All are strictly dominated by 30.
The idea is exactly the same as in the previous analysis.
We need to show that for all ,
Strictly Dominated Strategies in Reduced Game
To see this, for every , we show that
is strictly increasing in in the interval [0,30)
Take the derivative of the above with respect to :
As a result, all strategies are strictly dominated.
Pattern
Now a pattern emerges:
In the first step, we eliminated half of the strategies on the
right.
In the second step, we eliminated half of the strategies on the
left.
In the third step, we will eliminate half of the strategies on the
right.
We can keep doing this indefinitely, until we eliminate all but
one point.
What strategy remains?
Comparison with Benchmark
Notice that the prediction according to iterated strict dominance
is that each firm chooses .
So total supply is: 80.
Price under duopoly is 40.
In comparison with the monopoly model, a monopolist supplies
far less:
Monopolist only supplies .
Price under the monopolist is 60.
The monopolist’s price is far higher than under duopoly.
Consumers like more competition by the sellers because they
pay lower prices!
We will come back to this in a couple lectures to see the
intuition why.
4/4/2020 Originality Report
https://blackboard.nec.edu/webapps/mdb-sa-
BB5b75a0e7334a9/originalityReport/ultra?attemptId=b3332e05-
061b-4734-b229-6c6bae0fd3f2&course_i… 1/3
%33
%15
SafeAssign Originality Report
Ethical Hacking - 202030 - CRN122 - Zavgren • Wk 8 Research
Assignment
%48Total Score: High riskVenkata Ajey Bharghav Malladi
Submission UUID: a82b516e-2d5d-26c6-f2a5-bf288ae4c168
Total Number of Reports
1
Highest Match
48 %
Submission_Text.html
Average Match
48 %
Submitted on
04/04/20
06:25 PM CDT
Average Word Count
458
Highest: Submission_Text.html
%48Attachment 1
Global database (4)
Student paper Student paper Student paper
Student paper
Internet (3)
anith itworld reportcybercrime
Top sources (3)
Excluded sources (0)
View Originality Report - Old Design
Word Count: 458
Submission_Text.html
5 2 6
1
7 4 3
5 Student paper 2 Student paper 6 Student paper
https://blackboard.nec.edu/webapps/mdb-sa-
BB5b75a0e7334a9/originalityReport?attemptId=b3332e05-
061b-4734-b229-
6c6bae0fd3f2&course_id=_45761_1&download=true&includeD
eleted=true&print=true&force=true
4/4/2020 Originality Report
https://blackboard.nec.edu/webapps/mdb-sa-
BB5b75a0e7334a9/originalityReport/ultra?attemptId=b3332e05-
061b-4734-b229-6c6bae0fd3f2&course_i… 2/3
Source Matches (8)
Student paper 100%
Student paper 100%
reportcybercrime 100%
itworld 100%
Student paper 100%
Student paper 100%
A few years back, Equifax Inc. experienced a system breach that
compromised personally identifying data belonging to millions
of customers. For a couple of years,
the Equifax organization had been the leading organization
when it comes to credit reporting. Notably, its ability to assess
the financial health of multiple clients
established a strong background that influenced its rapid
growth. Despite knowing the increasing cyberattacks attributed
to the advancement of the technology,
Equifax faced a lax security posture that exposed multiple data
to attackers who were able to take hold of the security system
and extract terabytes of critical data
(Fruhlinger, 2020). The top executives in the organization were
blamed for this occurrence because it would have been
prevented had they taken the necessary
safeguards. The deep crisis happened for several months,
whereby it was initiated in March of 2017 and was discovered
in July, the same year.
The organization first experienced a hack via a consumer
complaint web portal where the attackers utilized a well- known
vulnerability to move from web portal to
other servers. This was facilitated by the fact that the systems
had not been adequately segmented, an aspect that made hackers
obtain the unencrypted usernames
and passwords, and eventually accessed the full policy. The
vulnerability could have been patched, but the organization had
not put such efforts. Hackers successfully
extracted the encrypted essential information for several months
bearing in mind that Equifax had not renewed encryption
certificate (Whittaker, 2018). It took only a
few months for the attackers to access the multiple Equifax
databases that possessed hundreds of millions of data belonging
to customers. Personally identifiable
information, including social security numbers and driver's
license numbers, was compromised and could be later used to
impersonate the customers. This aspect
could easily wreak havoc to one's records. This situation was
poorly handled because the management took the time to report
the incident, and this led to the
suspicion of whether the top executive was capable of managing
the crisis. If at all Equifax installed the upgraded Apache Struts
Software, this system breach could
have been prevented.
Link Used
1. https://techcrunch.com/2018/12/10/equifax-breach-
preventable-house-oversight-report/
2. https://www.csoonline.com/article/3444488/equifax-data-
breach-faq-what-happened-who-was-affected-what-was-the-
impact.html
References
Fruhlinger, J. (2020, February 12). Equifax data breach FAQ:
What happened, who was affected, what was the impact?
Retrieved from
https://www.csoonline.com/article/3444488/equifax-data-
breach-faq-what-happened-who-was-affected-what-was-the-
impact.html
Whittaker, Z. (2018, December 10). Equifax breach was
‘entirely preventable’ had it used basic security measures, says
house report – TechCrunch.
Retrieved from https://techcrunch.com/2018/12/10/equifax-
breach-preventable-house-oversight-report/
1
2
3 4 5
6 7 6
1
Student paper
https://techcrunch.com/2018/12/10/equif
ax-breach-preventable-house-oversight-
report/
Original source
https://techcrunch.com/2018/12/10/equif
ax-breach-preventable-house-oversight-
report/
2
Student paper
https://www.csoonline.com/article/34444
88/equifax-data-breach-faq-what-
happened-who-was-affected-what-was-
the-impact.html
Original source
https://www.csoonline.com/article/34444
88/equifax-data-breach-faq-what-
happened-who-was-affected-what-was-
the-impact.html
3
Student paper
(2020, February 12).
Original source
February 12, 2020
4
Student paper
Equifax data breach FAQ: What
happened, who was affected, what was
the impact?
Original source
Equifax data breach FAQ What
happened, who was affected, what was
the impact
5
Student paper
Retrieved from
https://www.csoonline.com/article/34444
88/equifax-data-breach-faq-what-
happened-who-was-affected-what-was-
the-impact.html
Original source
Retrieved from
https://www.csoonline.com/article/34444
88/equifax-data-breach-faq-what-
happened-who-was-affected-what-was-
the-impact.html
6
Student paper
(2018, December 10).
Original source
(2018, December 10)
4/4/2020 Originality Report
https://blackboard.nec.edu/webapps/mdb-sa-
BB5b75a0e7334a9/originalityReport/ultra?attemptId=b3332e05-
061b-4734-b229-6c6bae0fd3f2&course_i… 3/3
anith 100%
Student paper 100%
7
Student paper
Equifax breach was ‘entirely preventable’
had it used basic security measures, says
house report – TechCrunch.
Original source
Equifax breach was ‘entirely preventable’
had it used basic security measures, says
House report – TechCrunch
6
Student paper
Retrieved from
https://techcrunch.com/2018/12/10/equif
ax-breach-preventable-house-oversight-
report/
Original source
Retrieved from
https://techcrunch.com/2018/12/10/equif
ax-breach-preventable-house-oversight-
report/
Applications of Rationalizability and Iterated Dominance
Econ 402
Yuhta Ishii
Introduction
Last lecture: provided basic definitions of
rationalizability/iterated dominance in an abstract setting.
Key take aways:
rationalizability and iterated dominance are equivalent.
Sometimes rationalizability leads to unique prediction.
Sometimes, it doesn’t.
Today: Apply rationalizability in some concrete examples.
Reading: Chapter 8
Cournot Duopoly
Suppose that two firms produce the same product.
Firm 1 and 2 simultaneously choose respective quantities: .
No cost of production (for simplicity).
Given these quantities, the total quantity is and the price is
determined by the demand curve:
Cournot Duopoly
Since costs are zero, each firm’s utility function is just given
by:
How do firms choose quantity in this market?
Benchmark
Before we solve the duopoly model, suppose we just have a
monopolist:
One monopolist who faces a demand curve:
Monopolist does not face any competition.
How does such a monopolist choose quantity?
The Monopoly Case
The optimal quantity, , here satisfies:
Notice the usual tradeoff in the monopoly problem:
Higher quantity entails higher amount sold, but lower price.
The monopolist at optimum equates marginal revenue to
marginal cost.
Back to Duopoly
Now suppose that there are two firms in the market.
How does the amount supplied change?
To solve for the supply decisions of each firm, we use iterated
dominance/rationalizability.
Iterated Dominance/Rationalizability
We first look for the set :
The pure strategies that are not strictly dominated in the
original game.
To compute this set, we first look at pure strategies that are best
responses to a pure strategy of the opponent firm.
Best Responses
Suppose that you are firm 1 and that firm 2 produces .
Then what is firm 2’s best response?
To solve this, we need to solve the following problem:
The optimal quantity then is given by:
Best Responses
Suppose that you are firm 1 and that firm 2 produces .
Then what is firm 2’s best response?
Similarly, if firm 1 produces , the firm 2’s best response is:
Best Responses in Cournot Duopoly
Higher the quantity of the opponent, the less I want to produce:
Intuitively, higher quantity of the opponent decreases the price
lower marginal revenue.
Best Responses in Cournot Duopoly
Now using the above, we know that the quantities are all in .
These pure strategies are all best responses to some pure
strategy of firm 2.
What about the quantities ?
We know that such pure strategies are not best responses
against any pure strategy.
But we do not know whether they are best responses against a
mixed belief.
We now show that they are not, and in fact they are strictly
dominated.
Strictly Dominated Strategies in Cournot Duopoly
Claim: For any is strictly dominated by .
To prove this, we need to show that for all ,
To see this, note that if we take the derivative of the left hand
side with respect to , we get:
Strictly Dominated Strategies in Cournot
But for all and any .
This means that the utility function
Is strictly decreasing in in the interval for all values of .
Strictly Dominated Strategies in Cournot
This then means that: whenever for all ,
This shows that any pure strategy strictly above 60 is strictly
dominated.
Combined with our first observation, we see that
Similarly, .
Iterated Dominance
But with iterated dominance, we shouldn’t stop there.
Now we are faced with a smaller game where each player
chooses strategies in .
We look for strictly dominated strategies in this reduced game.
Strictly Dominated Strategies in Reduced Game
We first determine what pure strategies are the best responses to
pure strategies in this reduced game:
Now notice that all strategies in [30,60] are best responses to
pure strategies.
So .
What about ?
Strictly Dominated Strategies in Reduced Game
Claim: All are strictly dominated by 30.
The idea is exactly the same as in the previous analysis.
We need to show that for all ,
Strictly Dominated Strategies in Reduced Game
To see this, for every , we show that
is strictly increasing in in the interval [0,30)
Take the derivative of the above with respect to :
As a result, all strategies are strictly dominated.
Pattern
Now a pattern emerges:
In the first step, we eliminated half of the strategies on the
right.
In the second step, we eliminated half of the strategies on the
left.
In the third step, we will eliminate half of the strategies on the
right.
We can keep doing this indefinitely, until we eliminate all but
one point.
What strategy remains?
Comparison with Benchmark
Notice that the prediction according to iterated strict dominance
is that each firm chooses .
So total supply is: 80.
Price under duopoly is 40.
In comparison with the monopoly model, a monopolist supplies
far less:
Monopolist only supplies .
Price under the monopolist is 60.
The monopolist’s price is far higher than under duopoly.
Consumers like more competition by the sellers because they
pay lower prices!
We will come back to this in a couple lectures to see the
intuition why.
Applications of Rationalizability and Iterated Dominance
Econ 402
Yuhta Ishii
Introduction
Last lecture: provided basic definitions of
rationalizability/iterated dominance in an abstract setting.
Key take aways:
rationalizability and iterated dominance are equivalent.
Sometimes rationalizability leads to unique prediction.
Sometimes, it doesn’t.
Today: Apply rationalizability in some concrete examples.
Reading: Chapter 8
Cournot Duopoly
Suppose that two firms produce the same product.
Firm 1 and 2 simultaneously choose respective quantities: .
No cost of production (for simplicity).
Given these quantities, the total quantity is and the price is
determined by the demand curve:
Cournot Duopoly
Since costs are zero, each firm’s utility function is just given
by:
How do firms choose quantity in this market?
Benchmark
Before we solve the duopoly model, suppose we just have a
monopolist:
One monopolist who faces a demand curve:
Monopolist does not face any competition.
How does such a monopolist choose quantity?
The Monopoly Case
The optimal quantity, , here satisfies:
Notice the usual tradeoff in the monopoly problem:
Higher quantity entails higher amount sold, but lower price.
The monopolist at optimum equates marginal revenue to
marginal cost.
Back to Duopoly
Now suppose that there are two firms in the market.
How does the amount supplied change?
To solve for the supply decisions of each firm, we use iterated
dominance/rationalizability.
Iterated Dominance/Rationalizability
We first look for the set :
The pure strategies that are not strictly dominated in the
original game.
To compute this set, we first look at pure strategies that are best
responses to a pure strategy of the opponent firm.
Best Responses
Suppose that you are firm 1 and that firm 2 produces .
Then what is firm 2’s best response?
To solve this, we need to solve the following problem:
The optimal quantity then is given by:
Best Responses
Suppose that you are firm 1 and that firm 2 produces .
Then what is firm 2’s best response?
Similarly, if firm 1 produces , the firm 2’s best response is:
Best Responses in Cournot Duopoly
Higher the quantity of the opponent, the less I want to produce:
Intuitively, higher quantity of the opponent decreases the price
lower marginal revenue.
Best Responses in Cournot Duopoly
Now using the above, we know that the quantities are all in .
These pure strategies are all best responses to some pure
strategy of firm 2.
What about the quantities ?
We know that such pure strategies are not best responses
against any pure strategy.
But we do not know whether they are best responses against a
mixed belief.
We now show that they are not, and in fact they are strictly
dominated.
Strictly Dominated Strategies in Cournot Duopoly
Claim: For any is strictly dominated by .
To prove this, we need to show that for all ,
To see this, note that if we take the derivative of the left hand
side with respect to , we get:
Strictly Dominated Strategies in Cournot
But for all and any .
This means that the utility function
Is strictly decreasing in in the interval for all values of .
Strictly Dominated Strategies in Cournot
This then means that: whenever for all ,
This shows that any pure strategy strictly above 60 is strictly
dominated.
Combined with our first observation, we see that
Similarly, .
Iterated Dominance
But with iterated dominance, we shouldn’t stop there.
Now we are faced with a smaller game where each player
chooses strategies in .
We look for strictly dominated strategies in this reduced game.
Strictly Dominated Strategies in Reduced Game
We first determine what pure strategies are the best responses to
pure strategies in this reduced game:
Now notice that all strategies in [30,60] are best responses to
pure strategies.
So .
What about ?
Strictly Dominated Strategies in Reduced Game
Claim: All are strictly dominated by 30.
The idea is exactly the same as in the previous analysis.
We need to show that for all ,
Strictly Dominated Strategies in Reduced Game
To see this, for every , we show that
is strictly increasing in in the interval [0,30)
Take the derivative of the above with respect to :
As a result, all strategies are strictly dominated.
Pattern
Now a pattern emerges:
In the first step, we eliminated half of the strategies on the
right.
In the second step, we eliminated half of the strategies on the
left.
In the third step, we will eliminate half of the strategies on the
right.
We can keep doing this indefinitely, until we eliminate all but
one point.
What strategy remains?
Comparison with Benchmark
Notice that the prediction according to iterated strict dominance
is that each firm chooses .
So total supply is: 80.
Price under duopoly is 40.
In comparison with the monopoly model, a monopolist supplies
far less:
Monopolist only supplies .
Price under the monopolist is 60.
The monopolist’s price is far higher than under duopoly.
Consumers like more competition by the sellers because they
pay lower prices!
We will come back to this in a couple lectures to see the
intuition why.
Mixed Strategy Nash Equilibrium
Chapter 11
Yuhta Ishii
Economics 402
Introduction
So far, we have focused on Nash equilibria in pure strategies.
Each player plays a strategy with probability one.
Remember that some normal form games don’t have any Nash
equilibria in pure strategies.
E.g. matching pennies.
In contrast, there will always be a Nash equilibrium in mixed
strategies.
Matching Pennies
There is no NE in pure strategies
Game is a zero-sum game where whatever player 1 wins, player
2 loses.
The sum of payoffs in each cell is 0.
In many such games, typically there is no NE in pure strategies.
Once I know what the other player will play (which is the case
in NE), I never have an incentive to stay the ``loser’’.
Matching Pennies
In such games, randomization overcomes this problem.
There will always exist some NE in mixed strategies (could be
in pure strategies) in every finite normal form game.
In zero-sum games, this is natural.
For example, in matching pennies, you wouldn’t want to be
predictable in your play.
So you randomize.
Matching Pennies
Matching Pennies
Matching Pennies
Definition
Property 1: Relationship to (pure strategy) NE
As you might guess, any pure strategy NE (from previous
lectures) is still a mixed strategy NE.
A pure strategy NE is just a mixed strategy NE in which each
player plays a mixed strategy that assigns probability one to
exactly one strategy.
So mixed strategy NE are more general.
Property 2: Best Response Condition
Property 2: Best Response Condition
Property 3: Rationalizability
General Procedure for finding mixed strategy NE
Step 1: Find the set of rationalizable pure strategies by
performing iterated elimination of strictly dominated strategies.
Step 2: In the reduced game where each player only plays
rationalizable strategies, write equations for each players’
indifference conditions.
Step 3: Solve these equations to determine equilibrium
randomization probabilities.
Nash’s Theorem
The important discovery of Nash was the following theorem.
Nash’s theorem: Every finite normal form game (finite number
of players and finite number of strategies for each player) has at
least one Nash equilibrium in either pure strategies or mixed
strategies.
Example: Lobbying Game
Two firms simultaneously and independently decide whether to
lobby (L) or not (N) the government in hopes of trying to
generate favorable legislation.
Example 2: Tennis serves
Example 2: Tennis Serves
Example 3:
Compute all of the mixed strategy Nash equilibria of the above
game.
Nash Equilibrium
Yuhta Ishii
Econ 402
Pennsylvania State University
Introduction
Reading: Ch. 9, Ch. 10
So far we have restricted attention to the concept of
rationalizability (iterated elimination of strictly dominated
strategies) in analyzing
This however, has limitations for certain games:
Introduction (Cont.)
Recall that in the Battle of the Sexes,
The rationalizable strategy profiles are:
Note that at each rationalizable strategy profile, since each
strategy is rationalizable, there is a belief about opponent’s play
that rationalizes that strategy:
But at a strategy profile like , these beliefs are incorrect.
Introduction (Cont.)
The Nash equilibrium concept additionally imposes that indeed
these beliefs are correct.
John Nash in seminal work proposed the idea of a Nash
equilibrium.
Later won a Nobel prize in economics for this contribution.
Nowadays, Nash equilibrium is ubiquitous in economics.
Definition of Nash Equilibrium
A strategy profile, is a Nash equilibrium if for each player is
a best response against . In other words, for each , and all pure
strategies ,
In words, a strategy profile is a Nash equilibrium if every
player is playing a best response against the (correct) belief that
the opponents are playing the Nash equilibrium strategy profile.
Examples
Example 1:
Consider again the Battle of Sexes game.
Here the Nash equilibria are:
Notice that each of these strategy profiles are a rationalizable
strategy profile, but not all rationalizable strategy profiles are
Nash equilibria.
E.g. is not a Nash equilibrium.
Discussion
The last point is general and extremely important.
Nash equilibria are always rationalizable strategy profiles!
There may be rationalizable strategy profiles that are not Nash
equilibria.
You may think about why the above statement is true, the proof
is not too hard.
The above is useful because in looking for Nash equilibria, it is
oftentimes helpful to first compute the rationalizable strategies.
Then look for Nash equilibria within these rationalizable
strategies.
What is the number of Nash equilibria in these games?
1,2,1,1
2,2,1,1
2,2,2,1
2,2,1,2
1
2
3
4
What is the number of Nash equilibria in these games?
1,2,1,1
2,2,1,1
2,2,2,1
2,2,1,2
1
2
3
4
Midterm 1 Exam Info
Mean: 76
Standard Deviation: 23
Highest Score: 117
Will hand out the exams later.
If you’re really curious about your score, send me an email and
I can email you your score.
Midterm 1 Exam Info
How many Nash equilibria are there?
0
1
2
3
4
Another example
How many Nash equilibria are there?
0
1
2
3
4
Another example
Relationship between Rationalizability and NE (Nash equilibria)
Introduction
We discussed before that all Nash equilibria are rationalizable
strategy profiles.
So this means that:
In looking for NE, we can first find all the rationalizable
strategy profiles, and look for NE within the set of all
rationalizable strategy profiles.
Why are all NE rationalizable strategy profiles?
The idea is simple: suppose that is a NE.
By definition, is a best response against and similarly, is a
best response against .
This means that and are both not strictly dominated.
Why are all NE rationalizable strategy profiles?
As a result, both and survive the first round of elimination of
strictly dominated strategies.
But in the reduced game, neither nor are strictly dominated.
So again and survive the second round of elimination, etc.
So and survive every step of elimination: is a rationalizable
strategy profile.
Example:
The following game is a game to illustrate the above point
concretely.
The unique NE is: (B,Z).
Example:
We first eliminated X because it is strictly dominated by Z.
Notice that we don’t eliminate B nor Z.
Why?
Because B is a best response against Z, Z is a best response
against B.
Best responses to pure strategies are never eliminated.
Example:
In the second round, we eliminated A.
Notice that we don’t eliminate B nor Z again.
Why?
B and Z both survived first round.
In the reduced game, B is a best response against Z, Z is a best
response against B.
Best responses are not strictly dominated.
Example:
In the third round, we eliminate Y.
Notice that we don’t eliminate B nor Z again.
Why?
Same reasons as before.
Example:
In the third round, we eliminate Y.
Notice that we don’t eliminate B nor Z again.
Why?
Same reasons as before.
Nash Equilibria in Games with more players
So far, we have studied Nash equilibria in games with two
players.
Of course, Nash equilibria also applies to games with three or
more players.
Idea is exactly the same: it is strategy profile in which all
players are best responding against the Nash equilibrium
strategy profile of opponents.
Example: a simple partnership game
Three friends simultaneously decide whether to exert effort or
not. If all three friends exert effort, then they win a prize that
generates 100 utils for each friend. Otherwise, the friends do
not win any prize. Exerting effort is costly and decreases
utility by 1 util.
How many Nash equilibria does this game have?
More Applications of Nash Equilibrium
Cournot Duopoly
Recall the Cournot duopoly example that we analyzed using
rationalizability in the last lecture notes.
Let’s solve for the Nash equilibrium of this game.
Note that we already know that we’ll find (40,40):
We already know that the unique rationalizable strategy profile
was (40,40).
Finding this was a bit difficult.
But we can find the Nash equilibrium in a straightforward way.
Cournot Duopoly: Nash Equilibrium
Remember the definition of a Nash equilibrium.
is a Nash equilibrium if
is a best response against ;
And is a best response against .
Cournot Duopoly: Nash equilibrium
The fact that is a best response against means that:
solves the following maximization problem:
If firm 2 chooses , we solve for the best response by equating
the derivative of the above with respect to equal to zero:
Cournot Duopoly: Nash equilibrium
Solving for we get:
Similarly, we also get:
Cournot Duopoly: Nash equilibrium
If is a Nash equilibrium, then
;
.
Plugging in from before we get:
Cournot Duopoly: Nash Equilibrium
Solving for the simultaneously, we get:
One can also see Nash equilibrium as the intersection points of
the best response functions.
See graphs drawn in lecture.
Cournot Oligopoly: Nash Equilibrium
Lets extend this example a bit further.
This is additional material not covered in the book.
Suppose that the demand curve is the same as before, but now
there are three firms that are competing with each other.
Firm ’s utility function:
What are the Nash equilibria of this game?
Cournot Oligopoly: Nash Equilibrium
A Nash equilibrium is a triple such that
is a best response against ,
is a best response against
is a best response against .
As in the duopoly case, we solve for the best response of each
firm given an arbitrary choice of quantities by the opposing
firms.
Cournot Oligopoly: Nash Equilibrium
Suppose that firms and choose quantities and respectively.
What is the best response of firm 1?
Firm 1 wants to solve the following maximization problem:
To solve this, we set the derivative of the above with respect to
equal to zero:
Cournot Oligopoly: Nash Equilibrium
Solving for , we get the best response function:
Similarly, we get best response functions for 2 and 3:
Cournot Oligopoly: Nash Equilibrium
If is a Nash equilibrium, then we have to have the following
three equations satisfied simultaneously:
Solving for the Nash equilibrium is a matter of solving these
equations for three variables.
Cournot Oligopoly: Nash Equilibrium
Here we will solve for a symmetric Nash equilibrium.
A Nash equilibrium in which all firms choose the same quantity.
Turns out that all Nash equilibria will be symmetric, but don’t
worry about this.
If you’re curious, you can try to show that all Nash equilibria
must be symmetric.
Notice also that this was the case in the duopoly.
So if is a symmetric Nash equilibrium, then we must have:
Cournot Oligopoly: Nash Equilibrium
We then find that .
The unique symmetric Nash equilibrium is .
Compared to the duopoly case, each firm produces less.
However, the total supply with duopoly is 90.
The price is 30.
The price has lowered as a result of more competition!
This is consistent with the previous finding that duopoly
reduces the price relative to monopoly.
Cournot Oligopoly: Nash Equilibrium
We can extend this example even further.
Suppose that there are n firms.
Now solve for the symmetric Nash equilibria of this game.
You will find that the unique symmetric Nash equilibrium
satisfies:
So the unique symmetric Nash equilibrium is for every firm to
produce: .
Cournot Oligopoly: Nash Equilibrium
As a result, the total supply in the Nash equilibrium is:
The price in the Nash equilibrium is:
The price gets driven down to zero as n becomes arbitrarily
large.
More competition drives down the profits that each firm can
obtain in Nash equilibrium!
As becomes huge, these profits are driven down to zero!
Bertrand Duopoly
Another model of competition between two firms that is very
important is the Bertrand duopoly model.
In this model, firms decide on prices rather than quantities.
In a strategic situation involving multiple firms, this matters.
Remember with a monopolist, this didn’t matter.
Bertrand Duopoly
There are two firms.
Each firm simultaneously decides a price.
Both firms produce the same product, so consumers buy from
the firm with the lowest price:
If the firms choose the same price, half consumers go to 1 and
half buy from 2.
If the lowest price is , consumers’ demand:
Bertrand Duopoly
Suppose that each firm faces a marginal cost of production of
10.
So, the utility functions of the firm are:
What are all of the Nash equilibria of this game?
As before, we want to calculate the best responses for each
firm.
Given , the price of firm 2, what is the best response of firm 1?
Bertrand Duopoly: Monopoly Benchmark
Before beginning the analysis, lets solve again the monopoly
benchmark.
Suppose there’s only one firm selling to consumers who have an
inverse demand curve:
The firm has a marginal cost of 10.
Bertrand Duopoly: Monopoly Benchmark
The monopoly wants to maximize profits:
We solve this by differentiating the above with respect to and
setting it equal to zero:
Bertrand Duopoly: Monopoly Benchmark
So the monopolist
Charge a price of .
Supplies units.
Obtains a profit of
Bertrand Duopoly
Back to Bertrand duopoly, we need to calculate the best
response of firm 1 against the prices chosen by firm 2.
Case 1:
What is the best response?
Best response is . Why?
If the other firm is charging price above the monopoly price,
then I can obtain monopoly profits even if firm 1 charges
monopoly profits.
This is the best possible profits that firm 1 can obtain, so this is
the best response.
Bertrand Duopoly
Case 2:
What is the best response?
There is none! Why?
Bertrand Duopoly
Case 3:
In these cases, there is no best response for the same reason as
in Case 2.
Case 4:
Best responses here are any price 10 or above.
Why?
Case 5:
Best responses here are any price strictly above .
At such prices, firm 1 does not produce.
Bertrand Duopoly
So, the best response of firm 1 can be summarized as follows:
Best response of firm 2 can be summarized similarly.
Bertrand Duopoly: Nash Equilibrium
Having solved for the best responses of each firm, it is now
easy to see what the Nash equilibria are.
We can see it two ways:
Graphically, by seeing where the best response correspondences
cross.
Analytically, determined when a strategy profile is a mutual
best response.
Bertrand Duopoly: Nash Equilibrium
Given the previous we see that the unique Nash equilibrium is:
Each firm sets a price of 10, which is exactly equal to marginal
cost.
Bertrand Duopoly: Key Takeaways
Each firm chooses price at exactly marginal cost, 10.
The total supply is given by 110.
Profits for both firms are zero!
Bertrand Duopoly: Key Takeaways
Unlike in Cournot competition, introducing one more firm with
Bertrand competition drives the profits of all firms down to 0.
This is great for consumers since they now face lower prices.
Intuitively, with two firms, under Bertrand competition, as long
as the competitor is pricing above marginal cost, each firm has
an incentive to deviate to a price just below the price of the
competitor to capture the whole market.
In Cournot however, firms have to raise output (which leads to
a significant decrease in price) substantially in order to capture
more market share.
Bertrand Duopoly
Lets modify the example slightly.
Recall that in the example before, marginal costs were exactly
the same.
Fierce competition drove the prices offered by the firms to
marginal cost.
What if marginal costs differed across the two firms?
There are no Nash equilibria.
This seems problematic from an applied standpoint.
Applied analysis in Bertrand oftentimes assume that prices are
chosen from a discrete set.
E.g. prices must be set in increments of 1 dollar.
E.g. can’t set a price of .
Bertrand Duopoly with Different Marginal Costs
Suppose that firm 1 has marginal cost of 10 and firm 2 has
marginal cost of 20.
Demand remains the same:
Firm 1’s monopoly price is unchanged: .
Firm 2’s monopoly price is:
Bertrand Duopoly with Different Marginal Costs
The best response function of firm 1 is unchanged:
Bertrand Duopoly with Different Marginal Costs
The best response function of firm 2 is different since he has a
different marginal cost:
Best Response Curves
As you can see from the picture, there are no Nash equilibria.
This seems problematic for applications.
We can’t make a prediction of how firms will price.
Typically applications will discretize the price space as in the
following example.
Bertrand with Discrete Prices
There are two firms. Demand and firms’ marginal costs are the
same as before.
Suppose now that firm 1 can choose any positive integer price:
0,1,2,…
Similarly firm 2 can choose any positive integer price:
0,1,2,…
Neither firm can choose a price that involves decimals, e.g.
3.14.
Bertrand with Discrete Prices
With discrete prices, there is now many Nash equilibria.
Bertrand with Discrete Prices
With discrete prices, there is now many Nash equilibria.
Bertrand with Discrete Prices
As one can see from the picture of the best response curves,
note that there are many Nash equilibria.
The set of all Nash equilibria are:
Note that in all of these Nash equilibria, firm 1 (the firm with
the lower marginal cost) chooses the lower price and supplies
the whole market.
The firm with the lower marginal cost wins the whole market.
Bertrand with Multiple Firms
The Bertrand model, like the Cournot model can be extended to
arbitrarily many firms.
Suppose we have three firms all with the same marginal cost of
10.
What are the Nash equilibria of this game?
Cournot vs. Bertrand
Which one is more appropriate for applications?
This is important because the predictions substantially differ.
Typically depends on the market:
In industries such as automobiles, pharmaceuticals, etc., firms
cannot adjust quantities easily.
Cournot is better here.
Quantity is adjusted today and fixed throughout the production
cycle, and prices adjust to meet demand.
On the other hand, in markets where quantities can be adjusted
easily,
Bertrand is better.
Prices are set and quantities can be adjusted very easily to meet
demand.
Pareto Efficiency
Introduction
So far, we’ve talked about how we think players will play when
they play a game.
Main solution concepts: Rationalizability, Nash equilibrium.
We haven’t talked about whether what they actually play is
efficient.
Efficiency from a societal perspective.
In other words, what should players do to maximize ``societal
efficiency’’?
In contrast to Nash equilibrium, Pareto efficiency is a normative
concept.
NE: positive concept.
Pareto Efficiency: Definition
We say that a strategy profile Pareto dominates a strategy
profile if
for all player ;
for at least one player .
For example, in the Prisoner’s Dilemma, (Cooperate,Cooperate)
Pareto dominates (Defect, Defect).
Examples
Pareto Efficiency: Definition
We say that a strategy profile is Pareto efficient if there is no
that Pareto dominates .
It seems natural that we would not want the players to play a
strategy profile that is Pareto dominated.
So we want players to play (at the bare minimum) Pareto
efficient strategy profiles.
Of course, players do play Pareto dominated strategy profiles in
Nash equilibria, rationalizable strategy profiles, etc.
Examples
Pareto Efficiency vs. Nash equilibrium
Typically our predictions (Nash equilibrium, etc.) are not Pareto
efficient.
For example, Prisoner’s dilemma.
Pareto Efficiency vs. Nash equilibrium
Why are Nash equilibria sometimes not Pareto efficient?
Players in a Nash equilibria just maximize their own utility
(best responding to others’ behavior) without thinking about
how it impacts others’ utilities.
Your best response might actually really negatively impact
others’ utilities.
On the other hand, to determine Pareto efficiency, we think
about the possibility of making everyone weakly better off (and
at least one person strictly better off).
Pareto Efficiency vs. Nash equilibria
The discrepancy between Pareto efficiency and Nash equilibria:
Suggests an important role for policy interventions in game
settings.
Example via Prisoner’s Dilemma
Consider the Prisoner’s dilemma.
Now suppose that we are able to tax an individual for taking the
strategy .
In this case, the normal form of the game changes.
We are now able to sustain a new equilibrium of which Pareto
dominates the original equilibrium without the tax.
Interventions in a Coordination Game
Similarly consider the coordination game.
There are two Nash equilibria.
One of these is bad.
By imposing a tax on the bad action, we can change the game to
get rid of the bad Nash equilibrium.
In this new game, we expect players to always play the good
Nash equilibrium while in the original game, players may be
stuck in a bad Nash equilibrium.
Similar interventions can be done via subsidies or combination
of both taxes and subsidies.
Efficiency
Introduction
We have so far focused on: ``what do we think players will do
in a game?’’
We should probably also ask: ``what would be efficient for
players to play (from a societal perspective?’’
Rationalizability and Iterated Dominance
Economics 402 (Spring 2020)
Yuhta Ishii
Pennsylvania State University
Game
Guess a whole number between 1 and 100.
The person whose guess is closest to 2/3 of the average in the
classroom wins 10 dollars.
Write your name and your guess on a sheet and hand it in.
We will discuss this later in the class.
Introduction
We previously talked about the idea of strict dominance.
Rational behavior involves at least avoiding strictly dominated
strategies.
But sophisticated players reason beyond this.
Reading: Ch. 7
Example 1:
Suppose player 1 is rational.
Can we say which strategy he will choose?
No, for each of his strategies there is a belief that makes it
optimal.
Example 1:
What about player 2?
Can we say which strategy he will choose?
We don’t know for sure, but now we know that he will choose
only between and .
Example 1:
We as an analyst came to the conclusion that 2 will not play or
.
But since player 1 also knows that 2 is rational, and 2 has the
payoffs in the above normal form, he should also conclude that
will never play .
Example 1:
We as an analyst came to the conclusion that 2 will not play .
But since player 1 also knows that 2 is rational, and 2 has the
payoffs in the above normal form, he should also conclude that
will never play .
Example 1:
We as an analyst came to the conclusion that 2 will not play .
But since player 1 also knows that 2 is rational, and 2 has the
payoffs in the above normal form, he should also conclude that
will never play .
Example 1:
But now if 1 knows that 2 will never play , then player 1 should
never play .
is strictly dominated in this smaller game.
So if player 1 knows that player 2 is rational, and player 1 is
rational, then player 1 will never play .
Example 1:
Player 2 will then reason similarly: Player 2 knows
that player 1 knows that player 2 is rational.
that player 1 is rational.
So player 2 will realize that player 1 will never play .
Example 1:
Given this, player 2 will realize that he should play .
The only surviving strategy for player 1 is and the surviving
strategy for player 2 is .
This general procedure is what is called the iterated
elimination/deletion of strictly dominated strategies.
Iterated Elimination/Deletion of Strictly Dominated Strategies
Step 1: Delete all strictly dominated strategies for each player.
Call the set of strategies that remain for player .
Step 2: Consider the reduced game, where each player only
plays strategies in . Eliminate all strictly dominated strategies
for each player in this reduced game. Call the remaining
strategies for player , .
Repeat this process until no more strategies can be eliminated.
Call the surviving set of strategies for player , .
This set will be called the set of rationalizable strategies for
player i.
More on this name in the following slide.
Rationalizability
An alternative way to describe this iteration procedure is what
is called rationalizability.
Remember last time, we saw that:
a strategy is in if and only if it is also in .
In words, a strategy is not strictly dominated if and only if it is
a best response for some belief.
So the iterated elimination of strictly dominated strategies is the
same as the following procedure:
Rationalizability Procedure
Step 1: Keep all strategies that are best responses for some
belief. Call the set of strategies that are kept for player .
Step 2: Consider the reduced game, where each player only
plays strategies in . Keep for each player the set of strategies
that are best responses for some belief in the reduced game.
Call the remaining strategies for player , .
Repeat this process until no more strategies can be eliminated.
Call the surviving set of strategies for player , .
This set will be called the set of rationalizable strategies for
player i.
These are called rationalizable, because these are the strategies
that can be rationalized as best responses with some belief over
opponents’ rationalizable strategies.
Rationalizability and Iterated Elimination of Strictly Dominated
Strategies
As I said before, these two are exactly the same procedure,
because of the fact that .
So in order to find the rationalizable strategies, you can just
perform the iterated elimination of strictly dominated strategies.
Rationalizable Strategy Profiles
A strategy profile is rationalizable if each player plays a
rationalizable strategy.
We denote this set as .
For example, the rationalizable strategy profile in the above
game was: (B,Z).
Some Examples
Example 1
What are the rationalizable strategies for each player:
Example
What are the rationalizable strategies for each player:
Example 2
What are the rationalizable strategies for each player:
Example 2
What are the rationalizable strategies for each player:
Example 2
What are the rationalizable strategy profiles?
Example 2
What are the rationalizable strategy profiles?
Example 3:
What are the rationalizable strategy profiles of this game?
All strategy profiles
{(A,X), (A,Y), (B,X),(B,Y)}
{(A,X), (A,Y)}
{(A,X), (B,Y)}
Example 3:
What are the rationalizable strategy profiles of this game?
All strategy profiles
{(A,X), (A,Y), (B,X),(B,Y)}
{(A,X), (A,Y)}
{(A,X), (B,Y)}
What are the rationalizable strategies for each player?
Example: Eisner-Katzenberg game
Battle of the Sexes
What are the rationalizable strategies for each player?
,
,
Battle of the Sexes
What are the rationalizable strategies for each player?
,
,
Earn CASH in Business Studies!
Earn Cash by participating in
Business/Finance/Economics/Supply Chain/Accounting studies
in SMEAL.
In all these studies that typically last between ½ hour and 2
hours, participants earn CASH based upon the decisions they
make.
If you would like to sign up or learn more about them, go here
(this is open to anyone at Penn State):
https://lema.smeal.psu.edu/study
These are *not* for course credit and are completely voluntary.
If you would like more information, please contact Assistance
Professor of Business Economics, Chloe Tergiman, at
[email protected]
Common Knowledge
Introduction
The idea of common knowledge is at the heart of iterated
elimination/deletion of strictly dominated strategies (and thus
also rationalizability).
Some fact is common knowledge if
each player knows that fact;
each player knows that all players know the fact;
each player knows that all players know that all players know
the fact;
Etc.
Common Knowledge in Iterated Elimination
What we are assuming is that both payoffs and rationality are
common knowledge:
For example, we were able to delete in this game because we
assumed:
Player 2 knows both
that player 1 knows that player 2 is rational.
that player 1 is rational.
Common Knowledge Assumptions in Game Theory
Common knowledge assumption allow us to sharpen our
predictions:
We implicitly use it in iterated elimination of strictly dominated
strategies/rationalizability.
However, this is oftentimes a simplifying assumption:
Many economic contexts don’t feature common knowledge of
rationality or of payoffs.
We assume it for simplicity for now.
Much of modern game theory explores how to relax this
unrealistic assumption.
Hat Game
To illustrate the importance of common knowledge assumptions,
let’s play a game.
3 players.
Each player is given a hat to wear, which is either red or blue.
Each player cannot see the color of his own hat, but can see the
color of the other players’ hats.
Hat game: Analysis
Hat Game
There were three red hats: I denote this as (R,R,R)
I first asked each of you, ``Do you know the color of your own
hat?’’
Each one answered no.
Now when I announced that ``at least one of you is wearing a
red hat,’’ player 3 is able to conclude the color of his/her hat to
be red.
Why?
Hat Game
What’s going on? Consider the situation after I made the
announcement.
What is player 3 thinking?
He sees two red hats and so he knows that either the color
configuration is (R,R,R) or (R,R,B).
Hat Game
Suppose hypothetically that the true color configuration were
(R,R,B).
Let’s replay this game.
Player 1 would still be uncertain about his/her hat.
Claim: Player 2 would be able to tell that his/her hat is red.
Player 2 is uncertain in this situation between (R,R,B) and
(R,B,B)
Player 2 knows that because player 1 was uncertain, his hat
must be red.
Here player 2 knows that player 1 knows that there is at least
one red hat.
Hat Game
Given this, player 3 once (s)he sees that player 2 is uncertain,
should conclude that the true configuration is (R,R,R)!
What is going on?
Common Knowledge
The idea of common knowledge is much stronger than just the
idea of knowledge.
Notice that when I revealed to the players that ``there is at least
one person with a red hat,’’ I revealed some thing that everyone
already knew.
Yet, it had an effect on what player 3 was able to conclude!
Before the announcement, every player was uncertain about the
color of his/her hat.
Common Knowledge
What happened?
The revelation that ``at least one person is wearing a red hat’’
made this fact common knowledge.
Everyone already knew this fact.
But now everyone knows that everyone knows it.
Everyone knows that everyone knows that everyone knows it,
etc.
Common Knowledge
More precisely, consider the following statement:
“Player 2 knows that player 1 knows that there is at least one
red hat.”
This fact is uncertain to player 3 before the announcement.
The announcement made this statement certain to player 3.
This example illustrates the importance of not just knowledge
but common knowledge.
Back to the ``Choose 1-100 game.”
Why didn’t the prediction of the game coincide with what
actually happens in the classroom?
One reason why iterated deletion of strictly dominated
strategies may not be a good prediction is that typically in many
real world scenarios, rationality and the normal form are not
common knowledge.
Common Knowledge
Problem 1: [20 pts]
Part a: [10 pts] Consider the following normal form game,
which we call game G1:
D E
A 1, 1 0, 0
B 2, 1 −1,−1
Consider also a different normal form game in which player 1
has the additional option of playing
strategy C, which we call game G2:
D E
A 1, 1 0, 0
B 2, 1 −1,−1
C x, y a, b
Are there some possible values of x, y, a, b for which all of the
Nash equilibria of game G2 give
strictly worse payoff to player 1 (row player) than the Nash
equilibrium of game G1? If so, provide
an example of possible values of x, y, a, b. If not, justify why
not.
Part b: [10 pts] Consider the following normal form game.
L M R
U 1, 0 1, 2 0, 1
D 0, 3 0, 1 2, 0
K −1, 0 2, 0 3,−1
Find all the rationalizable strategies for players 1 (row player)
and 2 (column player). Justify your
answer, showing each step of elimination.
Part c: [10 pts, Extra Credit] Suppose that in a two player
normal form game player 1 has strategies
A1, B1, C1, D1 and player 2 has strategies A2, B2, C2, D2.
Suppose we know that in this game,
1. A1 is a best response to A2, B1 is a best response to B2;
2. and A2 is a best response to B1, B2 is a best response to A1.
Can we be sure that A1, B1, A2, B2 are rationalizable? If yes,
justify. If no, provide an explicit
example.
Problem 2: [20 pts] Consider the following n player game. Each
player has two pure strategies,
{0, 1}. The utilities of each player is as follows. Player 1
obtains 1 utility if he chooses a strategy
different from that chosen by player 2 and otherwise obtains a
utility of 0.1 Similarly, any player
i < n obtains a utility of 1 if he chooses a strategy different
from that chosen by player i + 1,
and otherwise obtains a utility of 0. Finally player n obtains a
utility of 1 if he chooses a strategy
different from that chosen by player 1, and otherwise obtains a
utility of 0.
Part a: [10 points] Find all Nash equilibria in pure strategies of
this game when n = 3. Justify both
why the Nash equilibria you found are Nash equilibria and why
there are no other Nash equilibria.
Part b: [10 points] Find all Nash equilibria in pure strategies of
this game when n = 4. Justify both
why the Nash equilibria you found are Nash equilibria and why
there are no other Nash equilibria.
1Note that the strategy of player 3 does not affect player 1’s
utility.
Problem 3: [30 pts] Consider two firms that compete via
Bertrand competition. The demand of
consumers is given by:
Q(p) = 150−p.
Firms 1 and 2 both have marginal costs of production of 15.
Each firm 1 and 2 choose prices p1 ≥ 0
and p2 ≥ 0 simultaneously. Consumers buy from the firm with
the lowest price. If the firms choose
the same price, then the firms share the consumers equally.
For example, if both firms choose a price of p1 = p2 = 20, then
each firm obtains profits of
150−20
2
(20−15).
Part a: [5 pts] Compute the best response functions of each firm
in this game.
Part b: [5 pts] What are all of the Nash equilibria of this game?
Justify your answer.
Part c: [5 pts] Are any of the Nash equilibria that you found in
part b Pareto efficient? If yes,
explain why. If not, provide an example of a strategy profile
that Pareto dominates each such Nash
equilibria.
Part d: [5 pts] Now suppose that each firm can only set prices in
increments of one dollar.2 What
are the Nash equilibria of this game?
Part e: [10 pts] Go back to the original game where firms can
set any price that is a positive real
number. Now suppose that another firm, firm 3, with marginal
cost 20 enters the market. All three
firms compete via Bertrand competition. Give an example of a
Nash equilibrium, and justify your
answer.
Problem 4: [30 pts] Two companies compete via Cournot
competition. Each firm simultaneously
chooses a quantity q1, q2 ≥ 0 to produce. Given quantities of
q1, q2 chosen by the two firms, each firm
can sell each of the units of the good at a price (in dollars)
given by the inverse demand function:
P(q1 + q2) = 150−q1 −q2.
Suppose that firm 1 has a marginal cost of production of 10
dollars and firm 2 has a marginal cost
of production of 20 dollars. As a result, each firm’s utility
(profit) is given by:
u1(q1, q2) = (150−q1 −q2)q1 −10q1
u2(q1, q2) = (150−q1 −q2)q2 −20q2.
Part a: [10 pts] Compute and write the best response function
for each firm. Show your work.
Part b: [10 pts] Solve for all of the Nash equilibria of this game.
What is the price that is charged
by the firms in this Nash equilibrium? Show your work.
Part c: [10 pts] Suppose now that the government thinks that
prices are too high because the firms
are producing too little. To incentivize more production, the
government implements a subsidy. For
each unit of the good sold, the government promises to pay each
firm an additional 5 dollars. What
are the Nash equilibria of this new game? Is the government
successful in lowering the prevailing
price?
2Prices must be some positive integer.

More Related Content

Similar to Applications of Rationalizability and Iterated DominanceEcon 4.docx

Sales Forecasting for Management Consultants & Business Analysts
Sales Forecasting for Management Consultants & Business AnalystsSales Forecasting for Management Consultants & Business Analysts
Sales Forecasting for Management Consultants & Business Analysts
Asen Gyczew
 
How To Write Without Plagiarism. APA Style Sixth Edition Resources ...
How To Write Without Plagiarism. APA Style Sixth Edition Resources ...How To Write Without Plagiarism. APA Style Sixth Edition Resources ...
How To Write Without Plagiarism. APA Style Sixth Edition Resources ...
Megan Jones
 
Design Thinking for the Business Case
Design Thinking for the Business CaseDesign Thinking for the Business Case
Design Thinking for the Business Case
Peer Insight | Innovation Consulting
 
Case exercise – issues list
Case exercise – issues listCase exercise – issues list
Case exercise – issues list
Ricardo Sosa
 
03 Analyzing The Problem
03 Analyzing The Problem03 Analyzing The Problem
03 Analyzing The Problem
Sandeep Ganji
 
Economics for entrepreneurs
Economics for entrepreneurs Economics for entrepreneurs
Economics for entrepreneurs
Dr. Trilok Kumar Jain
 
Essay For Gce O Level
Essay For Gce O LevelEssay For Gce O Level
Essay For Gce O Level
Jennifer Triepke
 
Eco 550 final exam 116 questions with answers 100% correct
Eco 550 final exam   116 questions with answers 100% correctEco 550 final exam   116 questions with answers 100% correct
Eco 550 final exam 116 questions with answers 100% correct
ProfessorLance
 

Similar to Applications of Rationalizability and Iterated DominanceEcon 4.docx (8)

Sales Forecasting for Management Consultants & Business Analysts
Sales Forecasting for Management Consultants & Business AnalystsSales Forecasting for Management Consultants & Business Analysts
Sales Forecasting for Management Consultants & Business Analysts
 
How To Write Without Plagiarism. APA Style Sixth Edition Resources ...
How To Write Without Plagiarism. APA Style Sixth Edition Resources ...How To Write Without Plagiarism. APA Style Sixth Edition Resources ...
How To Write Without Plagiarism. APA Style Sixth Edition Resources ...
 
Design Thinking for the Business Case
Design Thinking for the Business CaseDesign Thinking for the Business Case
Design Thinking for the Business Case
 
Case exercise – issues list
Case exercise – issues listCase exercise – issues list
Case exercise – issues list
 
03 Analyzing The Problem
03 Analyzing The Problem03 Analyzing The Problem
03 Analyzing The Problem
 
Economics for entrepreneurs
Economics for entrepreneurs Economics for entrepreneurs
Economics for entrepreneurs
 
Essay For Gce O Level
Essay For Gce O LevelEssay For Gce O Level
Essay For Gce O Level
 
Eco 550 final exam 116 questions with answers 100% correct
Eco 550 final exam   116 questions with answers 100% correctEco 550 final exam   116 questions with answers 100% correct
Eco 550 final exam 116 questions with answers 100% correct
 

More from ssusera34210

As described in Lecture Note 1, geography is a part of everyday life.docx
As described in Lecture Note 1, geography is a part of everyday life.docxAs described in Lecture Note 1, geography is a part of everyday life.docx
As described in Lecture Note 1, geography is a part of everyday life.docx
ssusera34210
 
As an extra credit, Must discuss at least one (1) o.docx
As an extra credit, Must discuss at least one (1) o.docxAs an extra credit, Must discuss at least one (1) o.docx
As an extra credit, Must discuss at least one (1) o.docx
ssusera34210
 
As an institution, Walden has long supported days of service and.docx
As an institution, Walden has long supported days of service and.docxAs an institution, Walden has long supported days of service and.docx
As an institution, Walden has long supported days of service and.docx
ssusera34210
 
As computer and internet technologies have advanced and become m.docx
As computer and internet technologies have advanced and become m.docxAs computer and internet technologies have advanced and become m.docx
As computer and internet technologies have advanced and become m.docx
ssusera34210
 
As cultural and literary scholar Louis Henry Gates  claims, Repetit.docx
As cultural and literary scholar Louis Henry Gates  claims, Repetit.docxAs cultural and literary scholar Louis Henry Gates  claims, Repetit.docx
As cultural and literary scholar Louis Henry Gates  claims, Repetit.docx
ssusera34210
 
As an African American male, social issues are some that seem to.docx
As an African American male, social issues are some that seem to.docxAs an African American male, social issues are some that seem to.docx
As an African American male, social issues are some that seem to.docx
ssusera34210
 
As a work teamDecide on the proto personas each team member .docx
As a work teamDecide on the proto personas each team member .docxAs a work teamDecide on the proto personas each team member .docx
As a work teamDecide on the proto personas each team member .docx
ssusera34210
 
As an astute social worker and professional  policy advocate, on.docx
As an astute social worker and professional  policy advocate, on.docxAs an astute social worker and professional  policy advocate, on.docx
As an astute social worker and professional  policy advocate, on.docx
ssusera34210
 
As a special education professional, it is important to be aware of .docx
As a special education professional, it is important to be aware of .docxAs a special education professional, it is important to be aware of .docx
As a special education professional, it is important to be aware of .docx
ssusera34210
 
As an incoming CEO, how would you have approached the senior leaders.docx
As an incoming CEO, how would you have approached the senior leaders.docxAs an incoming CEO, how would you have approached the senior leaders.docx
As an incoming CEO, how would you have approached the senior leaders.docx
ssusera34210
 
As a prison administrator (wardensuperintendent), what would your r.docx
As a prison administrator (wardensuperintendent), what would your r.docxAs a prison administrator (wardensuperintendent), what would your r.docx
As a prison administrator (wardensuperintendent), what would your r.docx
ssusera34210
 
As a helpful tool for schools, organizations, and agencies working w.docx
As a helpful tool for schools, organizations, and agencies working w.docxAs a helpful tool for schools, organizations, and agencies working w.docx
As a helpful tool for schools, organizations, and agencies working w.docx
ssusera34210
 
ArticleInterspecies ChimerismwithMammalian Pluripotent.docx
ArticleInterspecies ChimerismwithMammalian Pluripotent.docxArticleInterspecies ChimerismwithMammalian Pluripotent.docx
ArticleInterspecies ChimerismwithMammalian Pluripotent.docx
ssusera34210
 
As a future leader in the field of health care administration, you m.docx
As a future leader in the field of health care administration, you m.docxAs a future leader in the field of health care administration, you m.docx
As a future leader in the field of health care administration, you m.docx
ssusera34210
 
Article  Title  and  Date  of  the  Article   .docx
Article  Title  and  Date  of  the  Article   .docxArticle  Title  and  Date  of  the  Article   .docx
Article  Title  and  Date  of  the  Article   .docx
ssusera34210
 
Article The Effects of Color on the Moods of College .docx
Article The Effects of Color on the Moods  of College .docxArticle The Effects of Color on the Moods  of College .docx
Article The Effects of Color on the Moods of College .docx
ssusera34210
 
Art  museums  and art  galleries  are two different types of entitie.docx
Art  museums  and art  galleries  are two different types of entitie.docxArt  museums  and art  galleries  are two different types of entitie.docx
Art  museums  and art  galleries  are two different types of entitie.docx
ssusera34210
 
As a clinical social worker it is important to understand group .docx
As a clinical social worker it is important to understand group .docxAs a clinical social worker it is important to understand group .docx
As a clinical social worker it is important to understand group .docx
ssusera34210
 
artsArticleCircling Round Vitruvius, Linear Perspectiv.docx
artsArticleCircling Round Vitruvius, Linear Perspectiv.docxartsArticleCircling Round Vitruvius, Linear Perspectiv.docx
artsArticleCircling Round Vitruvius, Linear Perspectiv.docx
ssusera34210
 
Artists are often involved in national social movements that result .docx
Artists are often involved in national social movements that result .docxArtists are often involved in national social movements that result .docx
Artists are often involved in national social movements that result .docx
ssusera34210
 

More from ssusera34210 (20)

As described in Lecture Note 1, geography is a part of everyday life.docx
As described in Lecture Note 1, geography is a part of everyday life.docxAs described in Lecture Note 1, geography is a part of everyday life.docx
As described in Lecture Note 1, geography is a part of everyday life.docx
 
As an extra credit, Must discuss at least one (1) o.docx
As an extra credit, Must discuss at least one (1) o.docxAs an extra credit, Must discuss at least one (1) o.docx
As an extra credit, Must discuss at least one (1) o.docx
 
As an institution, Walden has long supported days of service and.docx
As an institution, Walden has long supported days of service and.docxAs an institution, Walden has long supported days of service and.docx
As an institution, Walden has long supported days of service and.docx
 
As computer and internet technologies have advanced and become m.docx
As computer and internet technologies have advanced and become m.docxAs computer and internet technologies have advanced and become m.docx
As computer and internet technologies have advanced and become m.docx
 
As cultural and literary scholar Louis Henry Gates  claims, Repetit.docx
As cultural and literary scholar Louis Henry Gates  claims, Repetit.docxAs cultural and literary scholar Louis Henry Gates  claims, Repetit.docx
As cultural and literary scholar Louis Henry Gates  claims, Repetit.docx
 
As an African American male, social issues are some that seem to.docx
As an African American male, social issues are some that seem to.docxAs an African American male, social issues are some that seem to.docx
As an African American male, social issues are some that seem to.docx
 
As a work teamDecide on the proto personas each team member .docx
As a work teamDecide on the proto personas each team member .docxAs a work teamDecide on the proto personas each team member .docx
As a work teamDecide on the proto personas each team member .docx
 
As an astute social worker and professional  policy advocate, on.docx
As an astute social worker and professional  policy advocate, on.docxAs an astute social worker and professional  policy advocate, on.docx
As an astute social worker and professional  policy advocate, on.docx
 
As a special education professional, it is important to be aware of .docx
As a special education professional, it is important to be aware of .docxAs a special education professional, it is important to be aware of .docx
As a special education professional, it is important to be aware of .docx
 
As an incoming CEO, how would you have approached the senior leaders.docx
As an incoming CEO, how would you have approached the senior leaders.docxAs an incoming CEO, how would you have approached the senior leaders.docx
As an incoming CEO, how would you have approached the senior leaders.docx
 
As a prison administrator (wardensuperintendent), what would your r.docx
As a prison administrator (wardensuperintendent), what would your r.docxAs a prison administrator (wardensuperintendent), what would your r.docx
As a prison administrator (wardensuperintendent), what would your r.docx
 
As a helpful tool for schools, organizations, and agencies working w.docx
As a helpful tool for schools, organizations, and agencies working w.docxAs a helpful tool for schools, organizations, and agencies working w.docx
As a helpful tool for schools, organizations, and agencies working w.docx
 
ArticleInterspecies ChimerismwithMammalian Pluripotent.docx
ArticleInterspecies ChimerismwithMammalian Pluripotent.docxArticleInterspecies ChimerismwithMammalian Pluripotent.docx
ArticleInterspecies ChimerismwithMammalian Pluripotent.docx
 
As a future leader in the field of health care administration, you m.docx
As a future leader in the field of health care administration, you m.docxAs a future leader in the field of health care administration, you m.docx
As a future leader in the field of health care administration, you m.docx
 
Article  Title  and  Date  of  the  Article   .docx
Article  Title  and  Date  of  the  Article   .docxArticle  Title  and  Date  of  the  Article   .docx
Article  Title  and  Date  of  the  Article   .docx
 
Article The Effects of Color on the Moods of College .docx
Article The Effects of Color on the Moods  of College .docxArticle The Effects of Color on the Moods  of College .docx
Article The Effects of Color on the Moods of College .docx
 
Art  museums  and art  galleries  are two different types of entitie.docx
Art  museums  and art  galleries  are two different types of entitie.docxArt  museums  and art  galleries  are two different types of entitie.docx
Art  museums  and art  galleries  are two different types of entitie.docx
 
As a clinical social worker it is important to understand group .docx
As a clinical social worker it is important to understand group .docxAs a clinical social worker it is important to understand group .docx
As a clinical social worker it is important to understand group .docx
 
artsArticleCircling Round Vitruvius, Linear Perspectiv.docx
artsArticleCircling Round Vitruvius, Linear Perspectiv.docxartsArticleCircling Round Vitruvius, Linear Perspectiv.docx
artsArticleCircling Round Vitruvius, Linear Perspectiv.docx
 
Artists are often involved in national social movements that result .docx
Artists are often involved in national social movements that result .docxArtists are often involved in national social movements that result .docx
Artists are often involved in national social movements that result .docx
 

Recently uploaded

ZK on Polkadot zero knowledge proofs - sub0.pptx
ZK on Polkadot zero knowledge proofs - sub0.pptxZK on Polkadot zero knowledge proofs - sub0.pptx
ZK on Polkadot zero knowledge proofs - sub0.pptx
dot55audits
 
Gender and Mental Health - Counselling and Family Therapy Applications and In...
Gender and Mental Health - Counselling and Family Therapy Applications and In...Gender and Mental Health - Counselling and Family Therapy Applications and In...
Gender and Mental Health - Counselling and Family Therapy Applications and In...
PsychoTech Services
 
Wound healing PPT
Wound healing PPTWound healing PPT
Wound healing PPT
Jyoti Chand
 
Philippine Edukasyong Pantahanan at Pangkabuhayan (EPP) Curriculum
Philippine Edukasyong Pantahanan at Pangkabuhayan (EPP) CurriculumPhilippine Edukasyong Pantahanan at Pangkabuhayan (EPP) Curriculum
Philippine Edukasyong Pantahanan at Pangkabuhayan (EPP) Curriculum
MJDuyan
 
Advanced Java[Extra Concepts, Not Difficult].docx
Advanced Java[Extra Concepts, Not Difficult].docxAdvanced Java[Extra Concepts, Not Difficult].docx
Advanced Java[Extra Concepts, Not Difficult].docx
adhitya5119
 
ANATOMY AND BIOMECHANICS OF HIP JOINT.pdf
ANATOMY AND BIOMECHANICS OF HIP JOINT.pdfANATOMY AND BIOMECHANICS OF HIP JOINT.pdf
ANATOMY AND BIOMECHANICS OF HIP JOINT.pdf
Priyankaranawat4
 
বাংলাদেশ অর্থনৈতিক সমীক্ষা (Economic Review) ২০২৪ UJS App.pdf
বাংলাদেশ অর্থনৈতিক সমীক্ষা (Economic Review) ২০২৪ UJS App.pdfবাংলাদেশ অর্থনৈতিক সমীক্ষা (Economic Review) ২০২৪ UJS App.pdf
বাংলাদেশ অর্থনৈতিক সমীক্ষা (Economic Review) ২০২৪ UJS App.pdf
eBook.com.bd (প্রয়োজনীয় বাংলা বই)
 
คำศัพท์ คำพื้นฐานการอ่าน ภาษาอังกฤษ ระดับชั้น ม.1
คำศัพท์ คำพื้นฐานการอ่าน ภาษาอังกฤษ ระดับชั้น ม.1คำศัพท์ คำพื้นฐานการอ่าน ภาษาอังกฤษ ระดับชั้น ม.1
คำศัพท์ คำพื้นฐานการอ่าน ภาษาอังกฤษ ระดับชั้น ม.1
สมใจ จันสุกสี
 
math operations ued in python and all used
math operations ued in python and all usedmath operations ued in python and all used
math operations ued in python and all used
ssuser13ffe4
 
RHEOLOGY Physical pharmaceutics-II notes for B.pharm 4th sem students
RHEOLOGY Physical pharmaceutics-II notes for B.pharm 4th sem studentsRHEOLOGY Physical pharmaceutics-II notes for B.pharm 4th sem students
RHEOLOGY Physical pharmaceutics-II notes for B.pharm 4th sem students
Himanshu Rai
 
Walmart Business+ and Spark Good for Nonprofits.pdf
Walmart Business+ and Spark Good for Nonprofits.pdfWalmart Business+ and Spark Good for Nonprofits.pdf
Walmart Business+ and Spark Good for Nonprofits.pdf
TechSoup
 
A Independência da América Espanhola LAPBOOK.pdf
A Independência da América Espanhola LAPBOOK.pdfA Independência da América Espanhola LAPBOOK.pdf
A Independência da América Espanhola LAPBOOK.pdf
Jean Carlos Nunes Paixão
 
Liberal Approach to the Study of Indian Politics.pdf
Liberal Approach to the Study of Indian Politics.pdfLiberal Approach to the Study of Indian Politics.pdf
Liberal Approach to the Study of Indian Politics.pdf
WaniBasim
 
Mule event processing models | MuleSoft Mysore Meetup #47
Mule event processing models | MuleSoft Mysore Meetup #47Mule event processing models | MuleSoft Mysore Meetup #47
Mule event processing models | MuleSoft Mysore Meetup #47
MysoreMuleSoftMeetup
 
The History of Stoke Newington Street Names
The History of Stoke Newington Street NamesThe History of Stoke Newington Street Names
The History of Stoke Newington Street Names
History of Stoke Newington
 
C1 Rubenstein AP HuG xxxxxxxxxxxxxx.pptx
C1 Rubenstein AP HuG xxxxxxxxxxxxxx.pptxC1 Rubenstein AP HuG xxxxxxxxxxxxxx.pptx
C1 Rubenstein AP HuG xxxxxxxxxxxxxx.pptx
mulvey2
 
IGCSE Biology Chapter 14- Reproduction in Plants.pdf
IGCSE Biology Chapter 14- Reproduction in Plants.pdfIGCSE Biology Chapter 14- Reproduction in Plants.pdf
IGCSE Biology Chapter 14- Reproduction in Plants.pdf
Amin Marwan
 
How to Make a Field Mandatory in Odoo 17
How to Make a Field Mandatory in Odoo 17How to Make a Field Mandatory in Odoo 17
How to Make a Field Mandatory in Odoo 17
Celine George
 
LAND USE LAND COVER AND NDVI OF MIRZAPUR DISTRICT, UP
LAND USE LAND COVER AND NDVI OF MIRZAPUR DISTRICT, UPLAND USE LAND COVER AND NDVI OF MIRZAPUR DISTRICT, UP
LAND USE LAND COVER AND NDVI OF MIRZAPUR DISTRICT, UP
RAHUL
 
BÀI TẬP DẠY THÊM TIẾNG ANH LỚP 7 CẢ NĂM FRIENDS PLUS SÁCH CHÂN TRỜI SÁNG TẠO ...
BÀI TẬP DẠY THÊM TIẾNG ANH LỚP 7 CẢ NĂM FRIENDS PLUS SÁCH CHÂN TRỜI SÁNG TẠO ...BÀI TẬP DẠY THÊM TIẾNG ANH LỚP 7 CẢ NĂM FRIENDS PLUS SÁCH CHÂN TRỜI SÁNG TẠO ...
BÀI TẬP DẠY THÊM TIẾNG ANH LỚP 7 CẢ NĂM FRIENDS PLUS SÁCH CHÂN TRỜI SÁNG TẠO ...
Nguyen Thanh Tu Collection
 

Recently uploaded (20)

ZK on Polkadot zero knowledge proofs - sub0.pptx
ZK on Polkadot zero knowledge proofs - sub0.pptxZK on Polkadot zero knowledge proofs - sub0.pptx
ZK on Polkadot zero knowledge proofs - sub0.pptx
 
Gender and Mental Health - Counselling and Family Therapy Applications and In...
Gender and Mental Health - Counselling and Family Therapy Applications and In...Gender and Mental Health - Counselling and Family Therapy Applications and In...
Gender and Mental Health - Counselling and Family Therapy Applications and In...
 
Wound healing PPT
Wound healing PPTWound healing PPT
Wound healing PPT
 
Philippine Edukasyong Pantahanan at Pangkabuhayan (EPP) Curriculum
Philippine Edukasyong Pantahanan at Pangkabuhayan (EPP) CurriculumPhilippine Edukasyong Pantahanan at Pangkabuhayan (EPP) Curriculum
Philippine Edukasyong Pantahanan at Pangkabuhayan (EPP) Curriculum
 
Advanced Java[Extra Concepts, Not Difficult].docx
Advanced Java[Extra Concepts, Not Difficult].docxAdvanced Java[Extra Concepts, Not Difficult].docx
Advanced Java[Extra Concepts, Not Difficult].docx
 
ANATOMY AND BIOMECHANICS OF HIP JOINT.pdf
ANATOMY AND BIOMECHANICS OF HIP JOINT.pdfANATOMY AND BIOMECHANICS OF HIP JOINT.pdf
ANATOMY AND BIOMECHANICS OF HIP JOINT.pdf
 
বাংলাদেশ অর্থনৈতিক সমীক্ষা (Economic Review) ২০২৪ UJS App.pdf
বাংলাদেশ অর্থনৈতিক সমীক্ষা (Economic Review) ২০২৪ UJS App.pdfবাংলাদেশ অর্থনৈতিক সমীক্ষা (Economic Review) ২০২৪ UJS App.pdf
বাংলাদেশ অর্থনৈতিক সমীক্ষা (Economic Review) ২০২৪ UJS App.pdf
 
คำศัพท์ คำพื้นฐานการอ่าน ภาษาอังกฤษ ระดับชั้น ม.1
คำศัพท์ คำพื้นฐานการอ่าน ภาษาอังกฤษ ระดับชั้น ม.1คำศัพท์ คำพื้นฐานการอ่าน ภาษาอังกฤษ ระดับชั้น ม.1
คำศัพท์ คำพื้นฐานการอ่าน ภาษาอังกฤษ ระดับชั้น ม.1
 
math operations ued in python and all used
math operations ued in python and all usedmath operations ued in python and all used
math operations ued in python and all used
 
RHEOLOGY Physical pharmaceutics-II notes for B.pharm 4th sem students
RHEOLOGY Physical pharmaceutics-II notes for B.pharm 4th sem studentsRHEOLOGY Physical pharmaceutics-II notes for B.pharm 4th sem students
RHEOLOGY Physical pharmaceutics-II notes for B.pharm 4th sem students
 
Walmart Business+ and Spark Good for Nonprofits.pdf
Walmart Business+ and Spark Good for Nonprofits.pdfWalmart Business+ and Spark Good for Nonprofits.pdf
Walmart Business+ and Spark Good for Nonprofits.pdf
 
A Independência da América Espanhola LAPBOOK.pdf
A Independência da América Espanhola LAPBOOK.pdfA Independência da América Espanhola LAPBOOK.pdf
A Independência da América Espanhola LAPBOOK.pdf
 
Liberal Approach to the Study of Indian Politics.pdf
Liberal Approach to the Study of Indian Politics.pdfLiberal Approach to the Study of Indian Politics.pdf
Liberal Approach to the Study of Indian Politics.pdf
 
Mule event processing models | MuleSoft Mysore Meetup #47
Mule event processing models | MuleSoft Mysore Meetup #47Mule event processing models | MuleSoft Mysore Meetup #47
Mule event processing models | MuleSoft Mysore Meetup #47
 
The History of Stoke Newington Street Names
The History of Stoke Newington Street NamesThe History of Stoke Newington Street Names
The History of Stoke Newington Street Names
 
C1 Rubenstein AP HuG xxxxxxxxxxxxxx.pptx
C1 Rubenstein AP HuG xxxxxxxxxxxxxx.pptxC1 Rubenstein AP HuG xxxxxxxxxxxxxx.pptx
C1 Rubenstein AP HuG xxxxxxxxxxxxxx.pptx
 
IGCSE Biology Chapter 14- Reproduction in Plants.pdf
IGCSE Biology Chapter 14- Reproduction in Plants.pdfIGCSE Biology Chapter 14- Reproduction in Plants.pdf
IGCSE Biology Chapter 14- Reproduction in Plants.pdf
 
How to Make a Field Mandatory in Odoo 17
How to Make a Field Mandatory in Odoo 17How to Make a Field Mandatory in Odoo 17
How to Make a Field Mandatory in Odoo 17
 
LAND USE LAND COVER AND NDVI OF MIRZAPUR DISTRICT, UP
LAND USE LAND COVER AND NDVI OF MIRZAPUR DISTRICT, UPLAND USE LAND COVER AND NDVI OF MIRZAPUR DISTRICT, UP
LAND USE LAND COVER AND NDVI OF MIRZAPUR DISTRICT, UP
 
BÀI TẬP DẠY THÊM TIẾNG ANH LỚP 7 CẢ NĂM FRIENDS PLUS SÁCH CHÂN TRỜI SÁNG TẠO ...
BÀI TẬP DẠY THÊM TIẾNG ANH LỚP 7 CẢ NĂM FRIENDS PLUS SÁCH CHÂN TRỜI SÁNG TẠO ...BÀI TẬP DẠY THÊM TIẾNG ANH LỚP 7 CẢ NĂM FRIENDS PLUS SÁCH CHÂN TRỜI SÁNG TẠO ...
BÀI TẬP DẠY THÊM TIẾNG ANH LỚP 7 CẢ NĂM FRIENDS PLUS SÁCH CHÂN TRỜI SÁNG TẠO ...
 

Applications of Rationalizability and Iterated DominanceEcon 4.docx

  • 1. Applications of Rationalizability and Iterated Dominance Econ 402 Yuhta Ishii Introduction Last lecture: provided basic definitions of rationalizability/iterated dominance in an abstract setting. Key take aways: rationalizability and iterated dominance are equivalent. Sometimes rationalizability leads to unique prediction. Sometimes, it doesn’t. Today: Apply rationalizability in some concrete examples. Reading: Chapter 8 Cournot Duopoly Suppose that two firms produce the same product. Firm 1 and 2 simultaneously choose respective quantities: . No cost of production (for simplicity). Given these quantities, the total quantity is and the price is determined by the demand curve: Cournot Duopoly Since costs are zero, each firm’s utility function is just given by:
  • 2. How do firms choose quantity in this market? Benchmark Before we solve the duopoly model, suppose we just have a monopolist: One monopolist who faces a demand curve: Monopolist does not face any competition. How does such a monopolist choose quantity? The Monopoly Case The optimal quantity, , here satisfies: Notice the usual tradeoff in the monopoly problem: Higher quantity entails higher amount sold, but lower price. The monopolist at optimum equates marginal revenue to marginal cost. Back to Duopoly Now suppose that there are two firms in the market. How does the amount supplied change? To solve for the supply decisions of each firm, we use iterated dominance/rationalizability. Iterated Dominance/Rationalizability We first look for the set :
  • 3. The pure strategies that are not strictly dominated in the original game. To compute this set, we first look at pure strategies that are best responses to a pure strategy of the opponent firm. Best Responses Suppose that you are firm 1 and that firm 2 produces . Then what is firm 2’s best response? To solve this, we need to solve the following problem: The optimal quantity then is given by: Best Responses Suppose that you are firm 1 and that firm 2 produces . Then what is firm 2’s best response? Similarly, if firm 1 produces , the firm 2’s best response is: Best Responses in Cournot Duopoly Higher the quantity of the opponent, the less I want to produce: Intuitively, higher quantity of the opponent decreases the price lower marginal revenue.
  • 4. Best Responses in Cournot Duopoly Now using the above, we know that the quantities are all in . These pure strategies are all best responses to some pure strategy of firm 2. What about the quantities ? We know that such pure strategies are not best responses against any pure strategy. But we do not know whether they are best responses against a mixed belief. We now show that they are not, and in fact they are strictly dominated. Strictly Dominated Strategies in Cournot Duopoly Claim: For any is strictly dominated by . To prove this, we need to show that for all , To see this, note that if we take the derivative of the left hand side with respect to , we get: Strictly Dominated Strategies in Cournot But for all and any . This means that the utility function Is strictly decreasing in in the interval for all values of .
  • 5. Strictly Dominated Strategies in Cournot This then means that: whenever for all , This shows that any pure strategy strictly above 60 is strictly dominated. Combined with our first observation, we see that Similarly, . Iterated Dominance But with iterated dominance, we shouldn’t stop there. Now we are faced with a smaller game where each player chooses strategies in . We look for strictly dominated strategies in this reduced game. Strictly Dominated Strategies in Reduced Game We first determine what pure strategies are the best responses to pure strategies in this reduced game: Now notice that all strategies in [30,60] are best responses to pure strategies. So . What about ? Strictly Dominated Strategies in Reduced Game Claim: All are strictly dominated by 30.
  • 6. The idea is exactly the same as in the previous analysis. We need to show that for all , Strictly Dominated Strategies in Reduced Game To see this, for every , we show that is strictly increasing in in the interval [0,30) Take the derivative of the above with respect to : As a result, all strategies are strictly dominated. Pattern Now a pattern emerges: In the first step, we eliminated half of the strategies on the right. In the second step, we eliminated half of the strategies on the left. In the third step, we will eliminate half of the strategies on the right. We can keep doing this indefinitely, until we eliminate all but one point. What strategy remains? Comparison with Benchmark Notice that the prediction according to iterated strict dominance
  • 7. is that each firm chooses . So total supply is: 80. Price under duopoly is 40. In comparison with the monopoly model, a monopolist supplies far less: Monopolist only supplies . Price under the monopolist is 60. The monopolist’s price is far higher than under duopoly. Consumers like more competition by the sellers because they pay lower prices! We will come back to this in a couple lectures to see the intuition why. 4/4/2020 Originality Report https://blackboard.nec.edu/webapps/mdb-sa- BB5b75a0e7334a9/originalityReport/ultra?attemptId=b3332e05- 061b-4734-b229-6c6bae0fd3f2&course_i… 1/3 %33 %15 SafeAssign Originality Report Ethical Hacking - 202030 - CRN122 - Zavgren • Wk 8 Research Assignment %48Total Score: High riskVenkata Ajey Bharghav Malladi Submission UUID: a82b516e-2d5d-26c6-f2a5-bf288ae4c168
  • 8. Total Number of Reports 1 Highest Match 48 % Submission_Text.html Average Match 48 % Submitted on 04/04/20 06:25 PM CDT Average Word Count 458 Highest: Submission_Text.html %48Attachment 1 Global database (4) Student paper Student paper Student paper Student paper Internet (3) anith itworld reportcybercrime Top sources (3) Excluded sources (0)
  • 9. View Originality Report - Old Design Word Count: 458 Submission_Text.html 5 2 6 1 7 4 3 5 Student paper 2 Student paper 6 Student paper https://blackboard.nec.edu/webapps/mdb-sa- BB5b75a0e7334a9/originalityReport?attemptId=b3332e05- 061b-4734-b229- 6c6bae0fd3f2&course_id=_45761_1&download=true&includeD eleted=true&print=true&force=true 4/4/2020 Originality Report https://blackboard.nec.edu/webapps/mdb-sa- BB5b75a0e7334a9/originalityReport/ultra?attemptId=b3332e05- 061b-4734-b229-6c6bae0fd3f2&course_i… 2/3 Source Matches (8) Student paper 100% Student paper 100% reportcybercrime 100% itworld 100%
  • 10. Student paper 100% Student paper 100% A few years back, Equifax Inc. experienced a system breach that compromised personally identifying data belonging to millions of customers. For a couple of years, the Equifax organization had been the leading organization when it comes to credit reporting. Notably, its ability to assess the financial health of multiple clients established a strong background that influenced its rapid growth. Despite knowing the increasing cyberattacks attributed to the advancement of the technology, Equifax faced a lax security posture that exposed multiple data to attackers who were able to take hold of the security system and extract terabytes of critical data (Fruhlinger, 2020). The top executives in the organization were blamed for this occurrence because it would have been prevented had they taken the necessary safeguards. The deep crisis happened for several months, whereby it was initiated in March of 2017 and was discovered in July, the same year. The organization first experienced a hack via a consumer complaint web portal where the attackers utilized a well- known vulnerability to move from web portal to other servers. This was facilitated by the fact that the systems had not been adequately segmented, an aspect that made hackers obtain the unencrypted usernames and passwords, and eventually accessed the full policy. The vulnerability could have been patched, but the organization had not put such efforts. Hackers successfully extracted the encrypted essential information for several months bearing in mind that Equifax had not renewed encryption certificate (Whittaker, 2018). It took only a
  • 11. few months for the attackers to access the multiple Equifax databases that possessed hundreds of millions of data belonging to customers. Personally identifiable information, including social security numbers and driver's license numbers, was compromised and could be later used to impersonate the customers. This aspect could easily wreak havoc to one's records. This situation was poorly handled because the management took the time to report the incident, and this led to the suspicion of whether the top executive was capable of managing the crisis. If at all Equifax installed the upgraded Apache Struts Software, this system breach could have been prevented. Link Used 1. https://techcrunch.com/2018/12/10/equifax-breach- preventable-house-oversight-report/ 2. https://www.csoonline.com/article/3444488/equifax-data- breach-faq-what-happened-who-was-affected-what-was-the- impact.html References Fruhlinger, J. (2020, February 12). Equifax data breach FAQ: What happened, who was affected, what was the impact? Retrieved from https://www.csoonline.com/article/3444488/equifax-data- breach-faq-what-happened-who-was-affected-what-was-the- impact.html Whittaker, Z. (2018, December 10). Equifax breach was ‘entirely preventable’ had it used basic security measures, says house report – TechCrunch.
  • 12. Retrieved from https://techcrunch.com/2018/12/10/equifax- breach-preventable-house-oversight-report/ 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 6 1 Student paper https://techcrunch.com/2018/12/10/equif ax-breach-preventable-house-oversight- report/ Original source https://techcrunch.com/2018/12/10/equif ax-breach-preventable-house-oversight- report/ 2 Student paper https://www.csoonline.com/article/34444 88/equifax-data-breach-faq-what- happened-who-was-affected-what-was- the-impact.html Original source
  • 13. https://www.csoonline.com/article/34444 88/equifax-data-breach-faq-what- happened-who-was-affected-what-was- the-impact.html 3 Student paper (2020, February 12). Original source February 12, 2020 4 Student paper Equifax data breach FAQ: What happened, who was affected, what was the impact? Original source Equifax data breach FAQ What happened, who was affected, what was the impact 5 Student paper Retrieved from https://www.csoonline.com/article/34444
  • 14. 88/equifax-data-breach-faq-what- happened-who-was-affected-what-was- the-impact.html Original source Retrieved from https://www.csoonline.com/article/34444 88/equifax-data-breach-faq-what- happened-who-was-affected-what-was- the-impact.html 6 Student paper (2018, December 10). Original source (2018, December 10) 4/4/2020 Originality Report https://blackboard.nec.edu/webapps/mdb-sa- BB5b75a0e7334a9/originalityReport/ultra?attemptId=b3332e05- 061b-4734-b229-6c6bae0fd3f2&course_i… 3/3 anith 100% Student paper 100% 7
  • 15. Student paper Equifax breach was ‘entirely preventable’ had it used basic security measures, says house report – TechCrunch. Original source Equifax breach was ‘entirely preventable’ had it used basic security measures, says House report – TechCrunch 6 Student paper Retrieved from https://techcrunch.com/2018/12/10/equif ax-breach-preventable-house-oversight- report/ Original source Retrieved from https://techcrunch.com/2018/12/10/equif ax-breach-preventable-house-oversight- report/ Applications of Rationalizability and Iterated Dominance Econ 402 Yuhta Ishii Introduction
  • 16. Last lecture: provided basic definitions of rationalizability/iterated dominance in an abstract setting. Key take aways: rationalizability and iterated dominance are equivalent. Sometimes rationalizability leads to unique prediction. Sometimes, it doesn’t. Today: Apply rationalizability in some concrete examples. Reading: Chapter 8 Cournot Duopoly Suppose that two firms produce the same product. Firm 1 and 2 simultaneously choose respective quantities: . No cost of production (for simplicity). Given these quantities, the total quantity is and the price is determined by the demand curve: Cournot Duopoly Since costs are zero, each firm’s utility function is just given by: How do firms choose quantity in this market? Benchmark Before we solve the duopoly model, suppose we just have a monopolist: One monopolist who faces a demand curve: Monopolist does not face any competition.
  • 17. How does such a monopolist choose quantity? The Monopoly Case The optimal quantity, , here satisfies: Notice the usual tradeoff in the monopoly problem: Higher quantity entails higher amount sold, but lower price. The monopolist at optimum equates marginal revenue to marginal cost. Back to Duopoly Now suppose that there are two firms in the market. How does the amount supplied change? To solve for the supply decisions of each firm, we use iterated dominance/rationalizability. Iterated Dominance/Rationalizability We first look for the set : The pure strategies that are not strictly dominated in the original game. To compute this set, we first look at pure strategies that are best responses to a pure strategy of the opponent firm.
  • 18. Best Responses Suppose that you are firm 1 and that firm 2 produces . Then what is firm 2’s best response? To solve this, we need to solve the following problem: The optimal quantity then is given by: Best Responses Suppose that you are firm 1 and that firm 2 produces . Then what is firm 2’s best response? Similarly, if firm 1 produces , the firm 2’s best response is: Best Responses in Cournot Duopoly Higher the quantity of the opponent, the less I want to produce: Intuitively, higher quantity of the opponent decreases the price lower marginal revenue. Best Responses in Cournot Duopoly Now using the above, we know that the quantities are all in . These pure strategies are all best responses to some pure strategy of firm 2. What about the quantities ? We know that such pure strategies are not best responses
  • 19. against any pure strategy. But we do not know whether they are best responses against a mixed belief. We now show that they are not, and in fact they are strictly dominated. Strictly Dominated Strategies in Cournot Duopoly Claim: For any is strictly dominated by . To prove this, we need to show that for all , To see this, note that if we take the derivative of the left hand side with respect to , we get: Strictly Dominated Strategies in Cournot But for all and any . This means that the utility function Is strictly decreasing in in the interval for all values of . Strictly Dominated Strategies in Cournot This then means that: whenever for all , This shows that any pure strategy strictly above 60 is strictly dominated.
  • 20. Combined with our first observation, we see that Similarly, . Iterated Dominance But with iterated dominance, we shouldn’t stop there. Now we are faced with a smaller game where each player chooses strategies in . We look for strictly dominated strategies in this reduced game. Strictly Dominated Strategies in Reduced Game We first determine what pure strategies are the best responses to pure strategies in this reduced game: Now notice that all strategies in [30,60] are best responses to pure strategies. So . What about ? Strictly Dominated Strategies in Reduced Game Claim: All are strictly dominated by 30. The idea is exactly the same as in the previous analysis. We need to show that for all , Strictly Dominated Strategies in Reduced Game To see this, for every , we show that
  • 21. is strictly increasing in in the interval [0,30) Take the derivative of the above with respect to : As a result, all strategies are strictly dominated. Pattern Now a pattern emerges: In the first step, we eliminated half of the strategies on the right. In the second step, we eliminated half of the strategies on the left. In the third step, we will eliminate half of the strategies on the right. We can keep doing this indefinitely, until we eliminate all but one point. What strategy remains? Comparison with Benchmark Notice that the prediction according to iterated strict dominance is that each firm chooses . So total supply is: 80. Price under duopoly is 40. In comparison with the monopoly model, a monopolist supplies far less: Monopolist only supplies . Price under the monopolist is 60.
  • 22. The monopolist’s price is far higher than under duopoly. Consumers like more competition by the sellers because they pay lower prices! We will come back to this in a couple lectures to see the intuition why. Applications of Rationalizability and Iterated Dominance Econ 402 Yuhta Ishii Introduction Last lecture: provided basic definitions of rationalizability/iterated dominance in an abstract setting. Key take aways: rationalizability and iterated dominance are equivalent. Sometimes rationalizability leads to unique prediction. Sometimes, it doesn’t. Today: Apply rationalizability in some concrete examples. Reading: Chapter 8 Cournot Duopoly Suppose that two firms produce the same product. Firm 1 and 2 simultaneously choose respective quantities: . No cost of production (for simplicity). Given these quantities, the total quantity is and the price is determined by the demand curve:
  • 23. Cournot Duopoly Since costs are zero, each firm’s utility function is just given by: How do firms choose quantity in this market? Benchmark Before we solve the duopoly model, suppose we just have a monopolist: One monopolist who faces a demand curve: Monopolist does not face any competition. How does such a monopolist choose quantity? The Monopoly Case The optimal quantity, , here satisfies: Notice the usual tradeoff in the monopoly problem: Higher quantity entails higher amount sold, but lower price. The monopolist at optimum equates marginal revenue to marginal cost. Back to Duopoly Now suppose that there are two firms in the market. How does the amount supplied change?
  • 24. To solve for the supply decisions of each firm, we use iterated dominance/rationalizability. Iterated Dominance/Rationalizability We first look for the set : The pure strategies that are not strictly dominated in the original game. To compute this set, we first look at pure strategies that are best responses to a pure strategy of the opponent firm. Best Responses Suppose that you are firm 1 and that firm 2 produces . Then what is firm 2’s best response? To solve this, we need to solve the following problem: The optimal quantity then is given by: Best Responses Suppose that you are firm 1 and that firm 2 produces . Then what is firm 2’s best response? Similarly, if firm 1 produces , the firm 2’s best response is:
  • 25. Best Responses in Cournot Duopoly Higher the quantity of the opponent, the less I want to produce: Intuitively, higher quantity of the opponent decreases the price lower marginal revenue. Best Responses in Cournot Duopoly Now using the above, we know that the quantities are all in . These pure strategies are all best responses to some pure strategy of firm 2. What about the quantities ? We know that such pure strategies are not best responses against any pure strategy. But we do not know whether they are best responses against a mixed belief. We now show that they are not, and in fact they are strictly dominated. Strictly Dominated Strategies in Cournot Duopoly Claim: For any is strictly dominated by . To prove this, we need to show that for all , To see this, note that if we take the derivative of the left hand side with respect to , we get: Strictly Dominated Strategies in Cournot But for all and any .
  • 26. This means that the utility function Is strictly decreasing in in the interval for all values of . Strictly Dominated Strategies in Cournot This then means that: whenever for all , This shows that any pure strategy strictly above 60 is strictly dominated. Combined with our first observation, we see that Similarly, . Iterated Dominance But with iterated dominance, we shouldn’t stop there. Now we are faced with a smaller game where each player chooses strategies in . We look for strictly dominated strategies in this reduced game. Strictly Dominated Strategies in Reduced Game We first determine what pure strategies are the best responses to pure strategies in this reduced game: Now notice that all strategies in [30,60] are best responses to pure strategies. So .
  • 27. What about ? Strictly Dominated Strategies in Reduced Game Claim: All are strictly dominated by 30. The idea is exactly the same as in the previous analysis. We need to show that for all , Strictly Dominated Strategies in Reduced Game To see this, for every , we show that is strictly increasing in in the interval [0,30) Take the derivative of the above with respect to : As a result, all strategies are strictly dominated. Pattern Now a pattern emerges: In the first step, we eliminated half of the strategies on the right. In the second step, we eliminated half of the strategies on the left. In the third step, we will eliminate half of the strategies on the right. We can keep doing this indefinitely, until we eliminate all but one point. What strategy remains?
  • 28. Comparison with Benchmark Notice that the prediction according to iterated strict dominance is that each firm chooses . So total supply is: 80. Price under duopoly is 40. In comparison with the monopoly model, a monopolist supplies far less: Monopolist only supplies . Price under the monopolist is 60. The monopolist’s price is far higher than under duopoly. Consumers like more competition by the sellers because they pay lower prices! We will come back to this in a couple lectures to see the intuition why. Mixed Strategy Nash Equilibrium Chapter 11 Yuhta Ishii Economics 402 Introduction So far, we have focused on Nash equilibria in pure strategies. Each player plays a strategy with probability one. Remember that some normal form games don’t have any Nash equilibria in pure strategies.
  • 29. E.g. matching pennies. In contrast, there will always be a Nash equilibrium in mixed strategies. Matching Pennies There is no NE in pure strategies Game is a zero-sum game where whatever player 1 wins, player 2 loses. The sum of payoffs in each cell is 0. In many such games, typically there is no NE in pure strategies. Once I know what the other player will play (which is the case in NE), I never have an incentive to stay the ``loser’’. Matching Pennies In such games, randomization overcomes this problem. There will always exist some NE in mixed strategies (could be in pure strategies) in every finite normal form game. In zero-sum games, this is natural. For example, in matching pennies, you wouldn’t want to be predictable in your play. So you randomize. Matching Pennies
  • 30. Matching Pennies Matching Pennies Definition Property 1: Relationship to (pure strategy) NE As you might guess, any pure strategy NE (from previous lectures) is still a mixed strategy NE. A pure strategy NE is just a mixed strategy NE in which each player plays a mixed strategy that assigns probability one to exactly one strategy. So mixed strategy NE are more general. Property 2: Best Response Condition Property 2: Best Response Condition Property 3: Rationalizability General Procedure for finding mixed strategy NE Step 1: Find the set of rationalizable pure strategies by performing iterated elimination of strictly dominated strategies. Step 2: In the reduced game where each player only plays rationalizable strategies, write equations for each players’ indifference conditions.
  • 31. Step 3: Solve these equations to determine equilibrium randomization probabilities. Nash’s Theorem The important discovery of Nash was the following theorem. Nash’s theorem: Every finite normal form game (finite number of players and finite number of strategies for each player) has at least one Nash equilibrium in either pure strategies or mixed strategies. Example: Lobbying Game Two firms simultaneously and independently decide whether to lobby (L) or not (N) the government in hopes of trying to generate favorable legislation. Example 2: Tennis serves Example 2: Tennis Serves Example 3: Compute all of the mixed strategy Nash equilibria of the above game.
  • 32. Nash Equilibrium Yuhta Ishii Econ 402 Pennsylvania State University Introduction Reading: Ch. 9, Ch. 10 So far we have restricted attention to the concept of rationalizability (iterated elimination of strictly dominated strategies) in analyzing This however, has limitations for certain games: Introduction (Cont.) Recall that in the Battle of the Sexes, The rationalizable strategy profiles are: Note that at each rationalizable strategy profile, since each strategy is rationalizable, there is a belief about opponent’s play that rationalizes that strategy: But at a strategy profile like , these beliefs are incorrect.
  • 33. Introduction (Cont.) The Nash equilibrium concept additionally imposes that indeed these beliefs are correct. John Nash in seminal work proposed the idea of a Nash equilibrium. Later won a Nobel prize in economics for this contribution. Nowadays, Nash equilibrium is ubiquitous in economics. Definition of Nash Equilibrium A strategy profile, is a Nash equilibrium if for each player is a best response against . In other words, for each , and all pure strategies , In words, a strategy profile is a Nash equilibrium if every player is playing a best response against the (correct) belief that the opponents are playing the Nash equilibrium strategy profile. Examples Example 1: Consider again the Battle of Sexes game. Here the Nash equilibria are: Notice that each of these strategy profiles are a rationalizable strategy profile, but not all rationalizable strategy profiles are Nash equilibria.
  • 34. E.g. is not a Nash equilibrium. Discussion The last point is general and extremely important. Nash equilibria are always rationalizable strategy profiles! There may be rationalizable strategy profiles that are not Nash equilibria. You may think about why the above statement is true, the proof is not too hard. The above is useful because in looking for Nash equilibria, it is oftentimes helpful to first compute the rationalizable strategies. Then look for Nash equilibria within these rationalizable strategies. What is the number of Nash equilibria in these games? 1,2,1,1 2,2,1,1 2,2,2,1
  • 35. 2,2,1,2 1 2 3 4 What is the number of Nash equilibria in these games? 1,2,1,1 2,2,1,1 2,2,2,1 2,2,1,2 1 2 3 4 Midterm 1 Exam Info Mean: 76 Standard Deviation: 23 Highest Score: 117 Will hand out the exams later. If you’re really curious about your score, send me an email and I can email you your score. Midterm 1 Exam Info How many Nash equilibria are there?
  • 36. 0 1 2 3 4 Another example How many Nash equilibria are there? 0 1 2 3 4 Another example Relationship between Rationalizability and NE (Nash equilibria) Introduction We discussed before that all Nash equilibria are rationalizable strategy profiles. So this means that: In looking for NE, we can first find all the rationalizable strategy profiles, and look for NE within the set of all rationalizable strategy profiles. Why are all NE rationalizable strategy profiles? The idea is simple: suppose that is a NE.
  • 37. By definition, is a best response against and similarly, is a best response against . This means that and are both not strictly dominated. Why are all NE rationalizable strategy profiles? As a result, both and survive the first round of elimination of strictly dominated strategies. But in the reduced game, neither nor are strictly dominated. So again and survive the second round of elimination, etc. So and survive every step of elimination: is a rationalizable strategy profile. Example: The following game is a game to illustrate the above point concretely. The unique NE is: (B,Z). Example: We first eliminated X because it is strictly dominated by Z. Notice that we don’t eliminate B nor Z. Why? Because B is a best response against Z, Z is a best response against B.
  • 38. Best responses to pure strategies are never eliminated. Example: In the second round, we eliminated A. Notice that we don’t eliminate B nor Z again. Why? B and Z both survived first round. In the reduced game, B is a best response against Z, Z is a best response against B. Best responses are not strictly dominated. Example: In the third round, we eliminate Y. Notice that we don’t eliminate B nor Z again. Why? Same reasons as before. Example: In the third round, we eliminate Y. Notice that we don’t eliminate B nor Z again. Why? Same reasons as before. Nash Equilibria in Games with more players So far, we have studied Nash equilibria in games with two
  • 39. players. Of course, Nash equilibria also applies to games with three or more players. Idea is exactly the same: it is strategy profile in which all players are best responding against the Nash equilibrium strategy profile of opponents. Example: a simple partnership game Three friends simultaneously decide whether to exert effort or not. If all three friends exert effort, then they win a prize that generates 100 utils for each friend. Otherwise, the friends do not win any prize. Exerting effort is costly and decreases utility by 1 util. How many Nash equilibria does this game have? More Applications of Nash Equilibrium Cournot Duopoly Recall the Cournot duopoly example that we analyzed using rationalizability in the last lecture notes. Let’s solve for the Nash equilibrium of this game. Note that we already know that we’ll find (40,40): We already know that the unique rationalizable strategy profile was (40,40). Finding this was a bit difficult. But we can find the Nash equilibrium in a straightforward way.
  • 40. Cournot Duopoly: Nash Equilibrium Remember the definition of a Nash equilibrium. is a Nash equilibrium if is a best response against ; And is a best response against . Cournot Duopoly: Nash equilibrium The fact that is a best response against means that: solves the following maximization problem: If firm 2 chooses , we solve for the best response by equating the derivative of the above with respect to equal to zero: Cournot Duopoly: Nash equilibrium Solving for we get: Similarly, we also get: Cournot Duopoly: Nash equilibrium If is a Nash equilibrium, then ; .
  • 41. Plugging in from before we get: Cournot Duopoly: Nash Equilibrium Solving for the simultaneously, we get: One can also see Nash equilibrium as the intersection points of the best response functions. See graphs drawn in lecture. Cournot Oligopoly: Nash Equilibrium Lets extend this example a bit further. This is additional material not covered in the book. Suppose that the demand curve is the same as before, but now there are three firms that are competing with each other. Firm ’s utility function: What are the Nash equilibria of this game? Cournot Oligopoly: Nash Equilibrium A Nash equilibrium is a triple such that is a best response against , is a best response against is a best response against . As in the duopoly case, we solve for the best response of each firm given an arbitrary choice of quantities by the opposing
  • 42. firms. Cournot Oligopoly: Nash Equilibrium Suppose that firms and choose quantities and respectively. What is the best response of firm 1? Firm 1 wants to solve the following maximization problem: To solve this, we set the derivative of the above with respect to equal to zero: Cournot Oligopoly: Nash Equilibrium Solving for , we get the best response function: Similarly, we get best response functions for 2 and 3: Cournot Oligopoly: Nash Equilibrium If is a Nash equilibrium, then we have to have the following three equations satisfied simultaneously: Solving for the Nash equilibrium is a matter of solving these equations for three variables. Cournot Oligopoly: Nash Equilibrium Here we will solve for a symmetric Nash equilibrium.
  • 43. A Nash equilibrium in which all firms choose the same quantity. Turns out that all Nash equilibria will be symmetric, but don’t worry about this. If you’re curious, you can try to show that all Nash equilibria must be symmetric. Notice also that this was the case in the duopoly. So if is a symmetric Nash equilibrium, then we must have: Cournot Oligopoly: Nash Equilibrium We then find that . The unique symmetric Nash equilibrium is . Compared to the duopoly case, each firm produces less. However, the total supply with duopoly is 90. The price is 30. The price has lowered as a result of more competition! This is consistent with the previous finding that duopoly reduces the price relative to monopoly. Cournot Oligopoly: Nash Equilibrium We can extend this example even further. Suppose that there are n firms. Now solve for the symmetric Nash equilibria of this game. You will find that the unique symmetric Nash equilibrium satisfies: So the unique symmetric Nash equilibrium is for every firm to
  • 44. produce: . Cournot Oligopoly: Nash Equilibrium As a result, the total supply in the Nash equilibrium is: The price in the Nash equilibrium is: The price gets driven down to zero as n becomes arbitrarily large. More competition drives down the profits that each firm can obtain in Nash equilibrium! As becomes huge, these profits are driven down to zero! Bertrand Duopoly Another model of competition between two firms that is very important is the Bertrand duopoly model. In this model, firms decide on prices rather than quantities. In a strategic situation involving multiple firms, this matters. Remember with a monopolist, this didn’t matter. Bertrand Duopoly There are two firms. Each firm simultaneously decides a price. Both firms produce the same product, so consumers buy from the firm with the lowest price: If the firms choose the same price, half consumers go to 1 and
  • 45. half buy from 2. If the lowest price is , consumers’ demand: Bertrand Duopoly Suppose that each firm faces a marginal cost of production of 10. So, the utility functions of the firm are: What are all of the Nash equilibria of this game? As before, we want to calculate the best responses for each firm. Given , the price of firm 2, what is the best response of firm 1? Bertrand Duopoly: Monopoly Benchmark Before beginning the analysis, lets solve again the monopoly benchmark. Suppose there’s only one firm selling to consumers who have an inverse demand curve: The firm has a marginal cost of 10. Bertrand Duopoly: Monopoly Benchmark The monopoly wants to maximize profits:
  • 46. We solve this by differentiating the above with respect to and setting it equal to zero: Bertrand Duopoly: Monopoly Benchmark So the monopolist Charge a price of . Supplies units. Obtains a profit of Bertrand Duopoly Back to Bertrand duopoly, we need to calculate the best response of firm 1 against the prices chosen by firm 2. Case 1: What is the best response? Best response is . Why? If the other firm is charging price above the monopoly price, then I can obtain monopoly profits even if firm 1 charges monopoly profits. This is the best possible profits that firm 1 can obtain, so this is the best response. Bertrand Duopoly Case 2: What is the best response? There is none! Why?
  • 47. Bertrand Duopoly Case 3: In these cases, there is no best response for the same reason as in Case 2. Case 4: Best responses here are any price 10 or above. Why? Case 5: Best responses here are any price strictly above . At such prices, firm 1 does not produce. Bertrand Duopoly So, the best response of firm 1 can be summarized as follows: Best response of firm 2 can be summarized similarly. Bertrand Duopoly: Nash Equilibrium Having solved for the best responses of each firm, it is now easy to see what the Nash equilibria are. We can see it two ways: Graphically, by seeing where the best response correspondences cross. Analytically, determined when a strategy profile is a mutual best response.
  • 48. Bertrand Duopoly: Nash Equilibrium Given the previous we see that the unique Nash equilibrium is: Each firm sets a price of 10, which is exactly equal to marginal cost. Bertrand Duopoly: Key Takeaways Each firm chooses price at exactly marginal cost, 10. The total supply is given by 110. Profits for both firms are zero! Bertrand Duopoly: Key Takeaways Unlike in Cournot competition, introducing one more firm with Bertrand competition drives the profits of all firms down to 0. This is great for consumers since they now face lower prices. Intuitively, with two firms, under Bertrand competition, as long as the competitor is pricing above marginal cost, each firm has an incentive to deviate to a price just below the price of the competitor to capture the whole market. In Cournot however, firms have to raise output (which leads to a significant decrease in price) substantially in order to capture more market share.
  • 49. Bertrand Duopoly Lets modify the example slightly. Recall that in the example before, marginal costs were exactly the same. Fierce competition drove the prices offered by the firms to marginal cost. What if marginal costs differed across the two firms? There are no Nash equilibria. This seems problematic from an applied standpoint. Applied analysis in Bertrand oftentimes assume that prices are chosen from a discrete set. E.g. prices must be set in increments of 1 dollar. E.g. can’t set a price of . Bertrand Duopoly with Different Marginal Costs Suppose that firm 1 has marginal cost of 10 and firm 2 has marginal cost of 20. Demand remains the same: Firm 1’s monopoly price is unchanged: . Firm 2’s monopoly price is: Bertrand Duopoly with Different Marginal Costs The best response function of firm 1 is unchanged: Bertrand Duopoly with Different Marginal Costs
  • 50. The best response function of firm 2 is different since he has a different marginal cost: Best Response Curves As you can see from the picture, there are no Nash equilibria. This seems problematic for applications. We can’t make a prediction of how firms will price. Typically applications will discretize the price space as in the following example. Bertrand with Discrete Prices There are two firms. Demand and firms’ marginal costs are the same as before. Suppose now that firm 1 can choose any positive integer price: 0,1,2,… Similarly firm 2 can choose any positive integer price: 0,1,2,… Neither firm can choose a price that involves decimals, e.g. 3.14. Bertrand with Discrete Prices With discrete prices, there is now many Nash equilibria.
  • 51. Bertrand with Discrete Prices With discrete prices, there is now many Nash equilibria. Bertrand with Discrete Prices As one can see from the picture of the best response curves, note that there are many Nash equilibria. The set of all Nash equilibria are: Note that in all of these Nash equilibria, firm 1 (the firm with the lower marginal cost) chooses the lower price and supplies the whole market. The firm with the lower marginal cost wins the whole market. Bertrand with Multiple Firms The Bertrand model, like the Cournot model can be extended to arbitrarily many firms. Suppose we have three firms all with the same marginal cost of 10. What are the Nash equilibria of this game? Cournot vs. Bertrand Which one is more appropriate for applications? This is important because the predictions substantially differ. Typically depends on the market: In industries such as automobiles, pharmaceuticals, etc., firms
  • 52. cannot adjust quantities easily. Cournot is better here. Quantity is adjusted today and fixed throughout the production cycle, and prices adjust to meet demand. On the other hand, in markets where quantities can be adjusted easily, Bertrand is better. Prices are set and quantities can be adjusted very easily to meet demand. Pareto Efficiency Introduction So far, we’ve talked about how we think players will play when they play a game. Main solution concepts: Rationalizability, Nash equilibrium. We haven’t talked about whether what they actually play is efficient. Efficiency from a societal perspective. In other words, what should players do to maximize ``societal efficiency’’? In contrast to Nash equilibrium, Pareto efficiency is a normative concept. NE: positive concept. Pareto Efficiency: Definition We say that a strategy profile Pareto dominates a strategy
  • 53. profile if for all player ; for at least one player . For example, in the Prisoner’s Dilemma, (Cooperate,Cooperate) Pareto dominates (Defect, Defect). Examples Pareto Efficiency: Definition We say that a strategy profile is Pareto efficient if there is no that Pareto dominates . It seems natural that we would not want the players to play a strategy profile that is Pareto dominated. So we want players to play (at the bare minimum) Pareto efficient strategy profiles. Of course, players do play Pareto dominated strategy profiles in Nash equilibria, rationalizable strategy profiles, etc. Examples Pareto Efficiency vs. Nash equilibrium Typically our predictions (Nash equilibrium, etc.) are not Pareto efficient. For example, Prisoner’s dilemma.
  • 54. Pareto Efficiency vs. Nash equilibrium Why are Nash equilibria sometimes not Pareto efficient? Players in a Nash equilibria just maximize their own utility (best responding to others’ behavior) without thinking about how it impacts others’ utilities. Your best response might actually really negatively impact others’ utilities. On the other hand, to determine Pareto efficiency, we think about the possibility of making everyone weakly better off (and at least one person strictly better off). Pareto Efficiency vs. Nash equilibria The discrepancy between Pareto efficiency and Nash equilibria: Suggests an important role for policy interventions in game settings. Example via Prisoner’s Dilemma Consider the Prisoner’s dilemma. Now suppose that we are able to tax an individual for taking the strategy . In this case, the normal form of the game changes. We are now able to sustain a new equilibrium of which Pareto dominates the original equilibrium without the tax. Interventions in a Coordination Game Similarly consider the coordination game. There are two Nash equilibria.
  • 55. One of these is bad. By imposing a tax on the bad action, we can change the game to get rid of the bad Nash equilibrium. In this new game, we expect players to always play the good Nash equilibrium while in the original game, players may be stuck in a bad Nash equilibrium. Similar interventions can be done via subsidies or combination of both taxes and subsidies. Efficiency Introduction We have so far focused on: ``what do we think players will do in a game?’’ We should probably also ask: ``what would be efficient for players to play (from a societal perspective?’’ Rationalizability and Iterated Dominance Economics 402 (Spring 2020) Yuhta Ishii Pennsylvania State University Game
  • 56. Guess a whole number between 1 and 100. The person whose guess is closest to 2/3 of the average in the classroom wins 10 dollars. Write your name and your guess on a sheet and hand it in. We will discuss this later in the class. Introduction We previously talked about the idea of strict dominance. Rational behavior involves at least avoiding strictly dominated strategies. But sophisticated players reason beyond this. Reading: Ch. 7 Example 1: Suppose player 1 is rational. Can we say which strategy he will choose? No, for each of his strategies there is a belief that makes it optimal. Example 1: What about player 2? Can we say which strategy he will choose? We don’t know for sure, but now we know that he will choose only between and .
  • 57. Example 1: We as an analyst came to the conclusion that 2 will not play or . But since player 1 also knows that 2 is rational, and 2 has the payoffs in the above normal form, he should also conclude that will never play . Example 1: We as an analyst came to the conclusion that 2 will not play . But since player 1 also knows that 2 is rational, and 2 has the payoffs in the above normal form, he should also conclude that will never play . Example 1: We as an analyst came to the conclusion that 2 will not play . But since player 1 also knows that 2 is rational, and 2 has the payoffs in the above normal form, he should also conclude that will never play . Example 1: But now if 1 knows that 2 will never play , then player 1 should never play . is strictly dominated in this smaller game. So if player 1 knows that player 2 is rational, and player 1 is
  • 58. rational, then player 1 will never play . Example 1: Player 2 will then reason similarly: Player 2 knows that player 1 knows that player 2 is rational. that player 1 is rational. So player 2 will realize that player 1 will never play . Example 1: Given this, player 2 will realize that he should play . The only surviving strategy for player 1 is and the surviving strategy for player 2 is . This general procedure is what is called the iterated elimination/deletion of strictly dominated strategies. Iterated Elimination/Deletion of Strictly Dominated Strategies Step 1: Delete all strictly dominated strategies for each player. Call the set of strategies that remain for player . Step 2: Consider the reduced game, where each player only plays strategies in . Eliminate all strictly dominated strategies for each player in this reduced game. Call the remaining strategies for player , . Repeat this process until no more strategies can be eliminated. Call the surviving set of strategies for player , . This set will be called the set of rationalizable strategies for player i. More on this name in the following slide. Rationalizability
  • 59. An alternative way to describe this iteration procedure is what is called rationalizability. Remember last time, we saw that: a strategy is in if and only if it is also in . In words, a strategy is not strictly dominated if and only if it is a best response for some belief. So the iterated elimination of strictly dominated strategies is the same as the following procedure: Rationalizability Procedure Step 1: Keep all strategies that are best responses for some belief. Call the set of strategies that are kept for player . Step 2: Consider the reduced game, where each player only plays strategies in . Keep for each player the set of strategies that are best responses for some belief in the reduced game. Call the remaining strategies for player , . Repeat this process until no more strategies can be eliminated. Call the surviving set of strategies for player , . This set will be called the set of rationalizable strategies for player i. These are called rationalizable, because these are the strategies that can be rationalized as best responses with some belief over opponents’ rationalizable strategies. Rationalizability and Iterated Elimination of Strictly Dominated Strategies As I said before, these two are exactly the same procedure, because of the fact that . So in order to find the rationalizable strategies, you can just perform the iterated elimination of strictly dominated strategies.
  • 60. Rationalizable Strategy Profiles A strategy profile is rationalizable if each player plays a rationalizable strategy. We denote this set as . For example, the rationalizable strategy profile in the above game was: (B,Z). Some Examples Example 1 What are the rationalizable strategies for each player: Example What are the rationalizable strategies for each player: Example 2 What are the rationalizable strategies for each player:
  • 61. Example 2 What are the rationalizable strategies for each player: Example 2 What are the rationalizable strategy profiles? Example 2 What are the rationalizable strategy profiles? Example 3: What are the rationalizable strategy profiles of this game? All strategy profiles
  • 62. {(A,X), (A,Y), (B,X),(B,Y)} {(A,X), (A,Y)} {(A,X), (B,Y)} Example 3: What are the rationalizable strategy profiles of this game? All strategy profiles {(A,X), (A,Y), (B,X),(B,Y)} {(A,X), (A,Y)} {(A,X), (B,Y)} What are the rationalizable strategies for each player? Example: Eisner-Katzenberg game Battle of the Sexes What are the rationalizable strategies for each player? , ,
  • 63. Battle of the Sexes What are the rationalizable strategies for each player? , , Earn CASH in Business Studies! Earn Cash by participating in Business/Finance/Economics/Supply Chain/Accounting studies in SMEAL. In all these studies that typically last between ½ hour and 2 hours, participants earn CASH based upon the decisions they make. If you would like to sign up or learn more about them, go here (this is open to anyone at Penn State): https://lema.smeal.psu.edu/study These are *not* for course credit and are completely voluntary. If you would like more information, please contact Assistance Professor of Business Economics, Chloe Tergiman, at [email protected] Common Knowledge Introduction
  • 64. The idea of common knowledge is at the heart of iterated elimination/deletion of strictly dominated strategies (and thus also rationalizability). Some fact is common knowledge if each player knows that fact; each player knows that all players know the fact; each player knows that all players know that all players know the fact; Etc. Common Knowledge in Iterated Elimination What we are assuming is that both payoffs and rationality are common knowledge: For example, we were able to delete in this game because we assumed: Player 2 knows both that player 1 knows that player 2 is rational. that player 1 is rational. Common Knowledge Assumptions in Game Theory Common knowledge assumption allow us to sharpen our predictions: We implicitly use it in iterated elimination of strictly dominated strategies/rationalizability.
  • 65. However, this is oftentimes a simplifying assumption: Many economic contexts don’t feature common knowledge of rationality or of payoffs. We assume it for simplicity for now. Much of modern game theory explores how to relax this unrealistic assumption. Hat Game To illustrate the importance of common knowledge assumptions, let’s play a game. 3 players. Each player is given a hat to wear, which is either red or blue. Each player cannot see the color of his own hat, but can see the color of the other players’ hats. Hat game: Analysis Hat Game There were three red hats: I denote this as (R,R,R) I first asked each of you, ``Do you know the color of your own hat?’’ Each one answered no. Now when I announced that ``at least one of you is wearing a
  • 66. red hat,’’ player 3 is able to conclude the color of his/her hat to be red. Why? Hat Game What’s going on? Consider the situation after I made the announcement. What is player 3 thinking? He sees two red hats and so he knows that either the color configuration is (R,R,R) or (R,R,B). Hat Game Suppose hypothetically that the true color configuration were (R,R,B). Let’s replay this game. Player 1 would still be uncertain about his/her hat. Claim: Player 2 would be able to tell that his/her hat is red. Player 2 is uncertain in this situation between (R,R,B) and (R,B,B) Player 2 knows that because player 1 was uncertain, his hat must be red. Here player 2 knows that player 1 knows that there is at least one red hat. Hat Game Given this, player 3 once (s)he sees that player 2 is uncertain, should conclude that the true configuration is (R,R,R)! What is going on?
  • 67. Common Knowledge The idea of common knowledge is much stronger than just the idea of knowledge. Notice that when I revealed to the players that ``there is at least one person with a red hat,’’ I revealed some thing that everyone already knew. Yet, it had an effect on what player 3 was able to conclude! Before the announcement, every player was uncertain about the color of his/her hat. Common Knowledge What happened? The revelation that ``at least one person is wearing a red hat’’ made this fact common knowledge. Everyone already knew this fact. But now everyone knows that everyone knows it. Everyone knows that everyone knows that everyone knows it, etc. Common Knowledge More precisely, consider the following statement: “Player 2 knows that player 1 knows that there is at least one red hat.” This fact is uncertain to player 3 before the announcement. The announcement made this statement certain to player 3. This example illustrates the importance of not just knowledge
  • 68. but common knowledge. Back to the ``Choose 1-100 game.” Why didn’t the prediction of the game coincide with what actually happens in the classroom? One reason why iterated deletion of strictly dominated strategies may not be a good prediction is that typically in many real world scenarios, rationality and the normal form are not common knowledge. Common Knowledge Problem 1: [20 pts] Part a: [10 pts] Consider the following normal form game, which we call game G1: D E A 1, 1 0, 0 B 2, 1 −1,−1 Consider also a different normal form game in which player 1 has the additional option of playing strategy C, which we call game G2:
  • 69. D E A 1, 1 0, 0 B 2, 1 −1,−1 C x, y a, b Are there some possible values of x, y, a, b for which all of the Nash equilibria of game G2 give strictly worse payoff to player 1 (row player) than the Nash equilibrium of game G1? If so, provide an example of possible values of x, y, a, b. If not, justify why not. Part b: [10 pts] Consider the following normal form game. L M R U 1, 0 1, 2 0, 1 D 0, 3 0, 1 2, 0 K −1, 0 2, 0 3,−1 Find all the rationalizable strategies for players 1 (row player) and 2 (column player). Justify your answer, showing each step of elimination. Part c: [10 pts, Extra Credit] Suppose that in a two player normal form game player 1 has strategies A1, B1, C1, D1 and player 2 has strategies A2, B2, C2, D2. Suppose we know that in this game, 1. A1 is a best response to A2, B1 is a best response to B2; 2. and A2 is a best response to B1, B2 is a best response to A1.
  • 70. Can we be sure that A1, B1, A2, B2 are rationalizable? If yes, justify. If no, provide an explicit example. Problem 2: [20 pts] Consider the following n player game. Each player has two pure strategies, {0, 1}. The utilities of each player is as follows. Player 1 obtains 1 utility if he chooses a strategy different from that chosen by player 2 and otherwise obtains a utility of 0.1 Similarly, any player i < n obtains a utility of 1 if he chooses a strategy different from that chosen by player i + 1, and otherwise obtains a utility of 0. Finally player n obtains a utility of 1 if he chooses a strategy different from that chosen by player 1, and otherwise obtains a utility of 0. Part a: [10 points] Find all Nash equilibria in pure strategies of this game when n = 3. Justify both why the Nash equilibria you found are Nash equilibria and why there are no other Nash equilibria. Part b: [10 points] Find all Nash equilibria in pure strategies of this game when n = 4. Justify both why the Nash equilibria you found are Nash equilibria and why there are no other Nash equilibria. 1Note that the strategy of player 3 does not affect player 1’s utility. Problem 3: [30 pts] Consider two firms that compete via Bertrand competition. The demand of consumers is given by:
  • 71. Q(p) = 150−p. Firms 1 and 2 both have marginal costs of production of 15. Each firm 1 and 2 choose prices p1 ≥ 0 and p2 ≥ 0 simultaneously. Consumers buy from the firm with the lowest price. If the firms choose the same price, then the firms share the consumers equally. For example, if both firms choose a price of p1 = p2 = 20, then each firm obtains profits of 150−20 2 (20−15). Part a: [5 pts] Compute the best response functions of each firm in this game. Part b: [5 pts] What are all of the Nash equilibria of this game? Justify your answer. Part c: [5 pts] Are any of the Nash equilibria that you found in part b Pareto efficient? If yes, explain why. If not, provide an example of a strategy profile that Pareto dominates each such Nash equilibria. Part d: [5 pts] Now suppose that each firm can only set prices in increments of one dollar.2 What are the Nash equilibria of this game? Part e: [10 pts] Go back to the original game where firms can set any price that is a positive real number. Now suppose that another firm, firm 3, with marginal
  • 72. cost 20 enters the market. All three firms compete via Bertrand competition. Give an example of a Nash equilibrium, and justify your answer. Problem 4: [30 pts] Two companies compete via Cournot competition. Each firm simultaneously chooses a quantity q1, q2 ≥ 0 to produce. Given quantities of q1, q2 chosen by the two firms, each firm can sell each of the units of the good at a price (in dollars) given by the inverse demand function: P(q1 + q2) = 150−q1 −q2. Suppose that firm 1 has a marginal cost of production of 10 dollars and firm 2 has a marginal cost of production of 20 dollars. As a result, each firm’s utility (profit) is given by: u1(q1, q2) = (150−q1 −q2)q1 −10q1 u2(q1, q2) = (150−q1 −q2)q2 −20q2. Part a: [10 pts] Compute and write the best response function for each firm. Show your work. Part b: [10 pts] Solve for all of the Nash equilibria of this game. What is the price that is charged by the firms in this Nash equilibrium? Show your work. Part c: [10 pts] Suppose now that the government thinks that prices are too high because the firms are producing too little. To incentivize more production, the government implements a subsidy. For each unit of the good sold, the government promises to pay each firm an additional 5 dollars. What are the Nash equilibria of this new game? Is the government
  • 73. successful in lowering the prevailing price? 2Prices must be some positive integer.