SlideShare a Scribd company logo
1 of 335
Is Marijuana a Gateway Drug?
Author(s): Jeffrey DeSimone
Source: Eastern Economic Journal, Vol. 24, No. 2 (Spring,
1998), pp. 149-164
Published by: Palgrave Macmillan Journals
Stable URL: http://www.jstor.org/stable/40325834 .
Accessed: 18/11/2014 03:18
Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the
Terms & Conditions of Use, available at .
http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp
.
JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars,
researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide
range of
content in a trusted digital archive. We use information
technology and tools to increase productivity and facilitate new
forms
of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please
contact [email protected]
.
Palgrave Macmillan Journals is collaborating with JSTOR to
digitize, preserve and extend access to Eastern
Economic Journal.
http://www.jstor.org
This content downloaded from 130.166.3.5 on Tue, 18 Nov 2014
03:18:48 AM
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
http://www.jstor.org/action/showPublisher?publisherCode=pal
http://www.jstor.org/stable/40325834?origin=JSTOR-pdf
http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp
http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp
IS MARIJUANA A GATEWAY DRUG?
Jeffrey DeSimone
Yale University
INTRODUCTION
Marijuana is by far the most widely-used illicit drug. Though
marijuana is a pow-
erful intoxicant with subjective psychedelic-like effects that are
more complicated
than those of alcohol or cocaine, research has yet to show that
marijuana consump-
tion has harmful consequences. In truth, the primary cause for
concern about mari-
juana use may be that it potentially leads to the use of more
hazardous illegal drugs
such as cocaine. This premise arises from evidence that the
overwhelming majority of
adolescent and young adult cocaine users have previously used
marijuana [O'Donnell
and Clayton, 1982; Mills and Noyes, 1984; Yamaguchi and
Kandel, 1984; Newcomb
and Bentler, 1986; Kandel and Yamaguchi, 1993] and is known
as the gateway hy-
pothesis. Since the use of cocaine is associated with problems
such as crime, child
poverty, poor neonatal health, and the spread of HIV, a gateway
effect of marijuana
on cocaine could signify a sizable social cost of marijuana use.
Prior marijuana consumption may, however, predict current
cocaine consump-
tion without necessarily causing it. Marijuana use may simply
be a marker of either
observable personal characteristics or unobservable factors that
make marijuana us-
ers more likely to progress to cocaine use [Kleiman, 1992].
Conversely, marijuana
may truly act as a gateway to cocaine in two fashions.
Marijuana intoxication may
spawn curiosity or diminish apprehension about trying more
dangerous drugs. Or,
the physiological and psychological benefits, say "euphoria"
(from Stigler and Becker
[1977]), induced by a certain level of marijuana consumption
may decline over time,
thereby prompting users to experiment with new drugs in an
attempt to regain their
original levels of euphoria [Kleiman, 1992].
The latter process above can be explained in terms of the
economic model of ad-
diction as specified by Becker and Murphy [1988] and
Chaloupka [1991]. In this model,
the cumulative past consumption of an addictive good
represents an "addictive stock"
that raises current consumption by creating both tolerance,
through a negative mar-
ginal utility, and reinforcement, through a positive effect on the
marginal utility of
current consumption. Grossman et al. [1996a] and Pacula [1997]
find that marijuana
is addictive in the sense that past use raises the likelihood of
current use. Addictive
marijuana can generate a gateway effect in two distinct ways.
One is simply through
contemporaneous complementarity of marijuana and cocaine.
The other is through a
direct positive effect of past marijuana consumption on the
marginal utility of current
Eastern Economic Journal, Vol. 24, No. 2, Spring 1998
149
This content downloaded from 130.166.3.5 on Tue, 18 Nov 2014
03:18:48 AM
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp
150 EASTERN ECONOMIC JOURNAL
consumption of other euphoria-producing goods such as
cocaine, which may occur
because the addictive stock is not of marijuana itself but rather
of the euphoria pro-
duced by marijuana. In this case, marijuana could conceivably
serve both as a gate-
way to cocaine and as a substitute to cocaine in the production
of euphoria [Kleiman,
1992]. Evidence of negative cross-price effects between the two
drugs, as reported by
DeSimone [1997], Grossman et al. [1996b] and Saffer and
Chaloupka [1996], implies
contemporaneous complementarity but is also consistent with a
direct intertemporal
relationship because none of these studies disentangles past and
current price ef-
fects.
In combination, then, the empirical findings of addictive
marijuana and negative
cross-price effects suggest a gateway effect of marijuana on
cocaine. Notwithstand-
ing, no formal econometric evidence of the intertemporal
relationship between the
two drugs has been obtained to this point. This paper provides
such evidence using
data from the National Longitudinal Survey of Youth (NLSY).
Though the study does
not attempt to identify the causal mechanisms by which
marijuana and cocaine are
related, it is the first to estimate a structural effect of past
marijuana demand on
current cocaine demand. The results provide strong
confirmation of the gateway hy-
pothesis.
EMPIRICAL SPECIFICATION
To econometrically test the gateway hypothesis, the current
demand for cocaine
must be estimated, for a sample of individuals who have not
previously used cocaine,
as a function of past marijuana demand and current values of
other variables that
influence cocaine use. Using the subscript t to denote the
current period and t -k to
denote the period k years in the past, current cocaine
consumption Ct is thus repre-
sented as a function of past marijuana consumption Mt_k and a
vector Xt of additional
exogenous determinants,
(1) Ct=b0 + btMt.h + b2Xt + e,
A gateway effect exists if b1 > 0 in equation (1).
Two empirical considerations make ordinary least squares
(OLS) estimation of
equation (1) inappropriate. First, marijuana use is a function of
many of the same
variables that determine cocaine use.1 Although OLS on
equation (1) holds Mt_k con-
stant while estimating the direct effect of variables in Xt, some
components of Xt may
concurrently affect Ct indirectly through Mt_k. More
importantly, Mt_k and Ct may be
spuriously correlated because of unobserved factors that
simultaneously affect the
use of both types of drugs. For instance, tastes for intoxication
or deviance are likely
to vary positively with both marijuana and cocaine use.
Meanwhile, other unobserved
factors may lead individuals to choose one drug over the other
as a producer of eupho-
ria. Since all previous users of cocaine are excluded from the
estimation sample,
unobservables may in this situation reflect a preference for
marijuana over cocaine in
period t -k because marijuana is less costly, less dangerous, less
stigmatized and more
easily obtained. The regression assumption that Mt_k and ec are
uncorrelated may
This content downloaded from 130.166.3.5 on Tue, 18 Nov 2014
03:18:48 AM
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp
IS MARIJUANA A GATEWAY DRUG? 15 1
thus be violated, resulting in bias and inconsistency in the OLS
estimates of the pa-
rameters of equation (1).
To account for the potential correlation between Mt_h and cc, a
two-stage instru-
mental variable (IV) regression procedure is employed. The first
stage equation rep-
resents past marijuana demand as a function of the exogenous
variables Xt that affect
current cocaine demand and a vector Zt_k of variables that
affect past marijuana de-
mand but not current cocaine demand,
(2) Mt_k = a0 + a2 X, + a2 Zt_k + em.
In theory the lagged values of X also belong on the right-hand
side of equation (2), but
are omitted from the empirical analysis because the variables in
X are either time-
invariant or highly correlated over time.2 Then, since the
predicted value of Mt_k in
equation (2) represents the component of Mt_k that is
uncorrelated with the unobserv-
able factors ec that impact Ct, equation (1) is typically
estimated using this predicted
value of Mt_k as a regressor in place of the observed Mt_k.
The second empirical concern is that Ct andMt_A are specified
as binary indicators
of drug use, since the gateway hypothesis posits a relationship
between the use, rather
than explicit quantities of consumption, of each drug.3 Because
Ct is binary, equation
(I) is most suitably estimated with a probit model. Smith and
Blundell [1986] and
Blundell and Smith [1989] show that equation (1) is
consistently estimated with a
probit that uses the observed value ofM^ but also includes the
residual term em from
equation (2),
(II) Ct = b0 + b1Muk + b2Xt + b3em + ec.
These studies also derive the expression for the correct
asymptotic covariance matrix
for the probit estimates of equation (I1). A limitation of this
procedure is its assump-
tion that the included endogenous variable, in this caseMt_ki is
fully observed. Equa-
tion (2) must therefore be estimated as a linear probability
model. In order to correct
for heteroskedasticity, equation (2) is first estimated by OLS to
obtain predicted val-
ues of Mt_k, and then reestimated by weighted least squares
using the inverse of these
predicted values as weights [Gujarati, 1995].
To improve on OLS, the set of instrumental variables Zt_k that
is excluded from
the cocaine demand equation must be highly correlated with
Mt_k but uncorrelated
with ec [Gujarati, 1995]. As is well known, nonzero correlation
of Zt_k and ec will ren-
der the IV estimates of equation (1) inconsistent. Moreover,
Bound et al. [1995] illus-
trates that the explanatory power of Zt_k is crucial for two
reasons. First, if Zt_k is only
weakly correlated with Mt_k, then even a weak correlation
between Z<jk and ec can
produce a large inconsistency in the IV estimates of equation
(1) that may even sur-
pass that of the OLS estimates. Second, IV estimates are biased
in finite samples, and
the magnitude of this bias approaches that of OLS as the
explanatory power of Zt_k
approaches zero. These empirical considerations must guide the
choice of Zt_k in the
analysis.
This content downloaded from 130.166.3.5 on Tue, 18 Nov 2014
03:18:48 AM
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp
152 EASTERN ECONOMIC JOURNAL
DATA
The primary source of data is the NLSY [Center for Human
Resource Research,
1995]. Since 1979, the NLSY annually has collected detailed
demographic and eco-
nomic information from a cohort of 12,686 individuals
originally aged between 14 and
22. In the 1984 and 1988 interviews, respondents were asked
about their current and
lifetime use of a variety of drugs, including marijuana and
cocaine. Consequently, the
relationship between cocaine demand in t=1988 and the demand
for marijuana k=4
years previously is estimated for respondents who report no
previous lifetime use of
cocaine in 1984. Past year rather than lifetime measures of drug
use are employed in
an attempt to restrict attention to individuals who are persistent
rather than experi-
mental drug users, following the interpretation of Saffer and
Chaloupka [1996] that
annual participation reflects at least occasional use. The
estimate here thus mea-
sures the gateway from recurrent marijuana to cocaine use,
which is more relevant
for drug policy than one that also encompasses experimental
drug use. As mentioned
earlier, the drug use variables are binary indicators of
consumption.
Note that NLSY respondents are between 23 and 31 years old in
1988, an impor-
tant consideration since all existing evidence of a marijuana
gateway comes based
upon responses from individuals in their teens and early
twenties. A specific concern
is that the sample is highly selective because cocaine initiation
declines with age in
the NLSY. More precisely, even though only 17 percent of the
respondents inter-
viewed in 1984 had previously used cocaine and are thus
excluded from the sample,
this group is almost four times as large as the number of
respondents in the sample
reporting past year use in 1988. The estimate of the gateway
effect reported here,
therefore, may not hold at younger ages or for the population in
general. In particu-
lar, given that past year marijuana prevalence in the NLSY also
fell over time, from
46 percent in 1980 to 32 percent in 1984, a gateway effect may
not be detectable
because precisely those individuals for whom the effect is likely
to be strongest are
not included in the sample.4 On the other hand, the finding of a
gateway effect would
mark an extension of the age range within which the
phenomenon is considered to be
consequential.
The set of explanatory variables included in the vector X^ is as
follows. Race is
represented by indicators of black and Hispanic ethnicity.
Educational attainment
measures human capital and is expected to be negatively
correlated with drug de-
mand, as is age and marriage. Males traditionally have higher
rates of drug use than
females. Indicators of living in a central city and in an SMSA
outside a central city
control for the possibility of increased availability of illegal
drugs in urban areas.
Indicators of a Catholic or nonreligious upbringing may reflect
the presence or ab-
sence of anti-drug values and attitudes. An indicator of the
presence of both parents
in the household at age fourteen is intended to capture parental
supervision and may
further capture family values that discourage drug use. Past year
earnings will be
positively associated with drug demand if drugs are normal
goods.6 In addition, esti-
mates of the average past year retail price of one pure gram of
cocaine, imputed for
over 140 cities using data from the Drug Enforcement
Administration (DEA) on pur-
chases made by undercover agents from 1977 to 1994, are
matched to the individual
This content downloaded from 130.166.3.5 on Tue, 18 Nov 2014
03:18:48 AM
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp
IS MARIJUANA A GATEWAY DRUG? 153
NLSY responses.6 As previously mentioned, values of all time-
varying variables are
taken from the 1988, or current period, interview.
The set of instruments 7*M that identify marijuana use includes
two measures of
state-level penalties for marijuana possession and two
additional variables that are
expected to affect marijuana use through their influence on
alcohol consumption. The
marijuana penalty variables, which pertain to the possession of
one ounce of mari-
juana for first-time offenders in the state of residence of the
respondent in 1984, are
the maximum prison term and an indicator that fines are not
assessed. Both of these
variables are components of the expected cost of marijuana use
and as such contrib-
ute to the full price of marijuana.7 The expected cost of
marijuana use, in terms of
time, lost wages and stigma from being arrested and sent to
prison, rises as the maxi-
mum prison term increases from zero in ten states to a year in
eighteen states and
more than that in six others. Similarly, the expected monetary
cost is lower in the two
states, Massachusetts and Oklahoma, in which no fine can be
levied compared to
other states in which the maximum fine ranges from $100 (in
ten states) to $2,500 or
more (in seven states).8 The alcohol-related variables are the
state excise tax on beer
and an indicator of parental alcoholism or problem drinking.
The beer tax is the tax
on a case of 24 twelve-ounce beers containing 3.2 percent
alcohol [Beer Institute,
1995]. If marijuana and alcohol are substitutes, as reported by
DiNardo and Lemieux
[1992], Model [1993] and Chaloupka and Laixuthai [1994], then
marijuana demand
will respond positively to increases in the beer tax, though
Saffer and Chaloupka
[1996] find evidence of the reverse relationship. Meanwhile,
Cadoret [1992] and
Merikangas et al. [1992] report an association between parental
alcohol problems
and filial drug use. This relationship may operate through
alcohol use, since the pre-
viously cited research on the chronological path of drug
initiation shows that alcohol
use almost always precedes the initiation of illegal drug use,
while Kenkel and Ribar
[1994] find that children of parents with alcohol problems are
more likely to consume
alcohol than others.
Although marijuana penalties could conceivably influence
cocaine and marijuana
use separately if they reflect sentiments towards illegal drug use
in general [Model,
1993], the exclusion of the two marijuana penalty variables
from the cocaine demand
equation is natural because their direct impact is on marijuana
demand. However,
the exclusion of the two alcohol-related variables is more
questionable. The rationale
is the expectation that the consumption of alcohol is more
closely related with that of
marijuana than that of other illegal drugs like cocaine that are
more dangerous and
less socially acceptable. Besides evidence that alcohol use
usually precedes the initia-
tion of marijuana use even for the large fraction of marijuana
users who do not progress
to cocaine use, additional support for this exclusion strategy is
given by Mills and
Noyes [1984], Yamaguchi and Kandel [1984] and Newcomb and
Bentler [1986], who
fail to find a direct connection between past alcohol and current
cocaine use. Never-
theless, the propriety of this restriction and the full set of
exclusions is empirically
tested below, as is the power of the marijuana penalty variables
and the full set of
excluded instruments Z^ to explain the variation in marijuana
use.
This content downloaded from 130.166.3.5 on Tue, 18 Nov 2014
03:18:48 AM
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp
154 EASTERN ECONOMIC JOURNAL
TABLE 1
Descriptive Statistics
(n=7,279)
Standard
Mean Deviation
Dependent Variables
Used Cocaine Past Year 0.057 0.232
Used Marijuana Past Year (in 1984) 0.246 0.431
Explanatory Variables
Age 27.005 2.265
Education 12.683 2.437
Male 0.443 0.497
Black 0.270 0.444
Hispanic 0.162 0.368
Married 0.482 0.500
Central City Residence 0.143 0.350
SMSA Residence 0.595 0.491
Catholic Background 0.323 0.468
No Religious Background 0.039 0.193
Earnings Past Year (in 1000s) 17.663 15.111
Cocaine Price 123.620 30.144
Both Parents Present Age 14 0.691 0.462
Excluded Instrumental Variables
Alcoholic Parent 0.215 0.411
Beer Tax (in 1984) 0.540 0.621
Maximum Jail Time for Marijuana (in 1984) 0.775 1.269
No Fine for Marijuana (in 1984) 0.036 0.187
Table 1 presents the means and standard deviations of the
variables included in
the analysis for the 7,279 respondents with complete data.9
Almost a quarter of the
sample used marijuana in the year prior to the 1984 interview,
but fewer than 6
percent used cocaine in the year preceding the 1988 interview.
Table 2 exhibits the
joint frequency of past marijuana and current cocaine demand.
Even though 1984
marijuana nonusers outnumber users by a three-to-one margin,
almost two-thirds of
those who consumed cocaine in 1988 also consumed marijuana
in 1984. A chi-square
test of independence formally rejects the hypothesis that
marijuana users are no more
likely than nonusers to progress to cocaine use. However, more
rigorous examination
is necessary to determine whether this preliminary evidence of a
gateway effect actu-
ally represents a causal relationship.
A final point before proceeding to the regression results is that
since drug use is
an illegal activity, it may be underreported by NLSY
respondents. Some evidence of
underreporting exists for lifetime cocaine use in 1984 [Mensch
and Kandel, 1988] and
for both lifetime and past month marijuana and cocaine use, in
both 1984 and 1988,
in the modest (around 9 percent) fraction of interviews in which
parents are present
This content downloaded from 130.166.3.5 on Tue, 18 Nov 2014
03:18:48 AM
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp
IS MARIJUANA A GATEWAY DRUG? 155
TABLE 2
Joint Frequencies of Marijuana and Cocaine Use
Used Cocaine Past Year 1988
Yes No Total
Used Marijuana Past Year 1984
Yes 270 1522 1792
No 147 5340 5487
Total 417 6862 7279
Chi-Squared Test of Independence: 2(1) = 383.8, p = 0.000
or that take place over the telephone [Hoyt and Chaloupka,
1994]. However, Sickles
and Taubman [1991] provide evidence that reported past year
drug use should be
fairly accurate in both years. Furthermore, as long as marijuana
use is truthfully
reported, underreporting of 1988 cocaine use will only bias the
estimate of the gate-
way effect if this underreporting is correlated with 1984
marijuana use. But if the
strong association between marijuana and cocaine use recorded
in Table 2 also holds
for cocaine users who report not using cocaine, so that
marijuana users are more
likely than nonusers to underreport cocaine, then the effect of
underreporting of 1988
cocaine use but not 1984 marijuana use is to bias the estimated
gateway coefficient
towards zero.10 Such downward bias is exacerbated if lifetime
cocaine use in 1984 is
also underreported, as suggested by evidence from Johnston et
al. [1988] that respon-
dents who lie do so consistently over time, because the primary
effect of underreporting
in this case is to count respondents as current cocaine nonusers
when in fact they
should be excluded from the sample.11
RESULTS
Table 3 displays the regression results. Column 1 shows the
estimates of equation
(2), the first stage equation for marijuana use in 1984. The
variables of primary con-
cern are the excluded instruments Z^. The signs are as
anticipated for the three of
these variables for which prior expectations of the sign exist.
The predicted likelihood
of marijuana use is 3 percent lower in Nevada, which has the
highest maximum prison
term of six years, than in the ten states in which first-time
marijuana possession
offenses carry no prison sentence. The coefficient approaches
statistical significance
with ap-value of 0.136. The remaining three identifying
instruments are statistically
significant at all conventional confidence levels. Having an
alcoholic parent increases
the probability of marijuana consumption slightly more than
living in a state with no
fines for first-time marijuana possession. Meanwhile, the
coefficient of the beer tax
predicts that marijuana consumption is over 4 percent more
probable in Wyoming,
which has the lowest beer tax of $0.04, than in Alabama, which
has the highest of
$2.28. Although this evidence of complementarity between
alcohol and marijuana
contradicts the findings of DiNardo and Lemieux [1992], Model
[1993] and Chaloupka
and Laixuthai [1994], this result may not generalize because of
the selection of the
sample used here.
This content downloaded from 130.166.3.5 on Tue, 18 Nov 2014
03:18:48 AM
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp
156 EASTERN ECONOMIC JOURNAL
TABLE 3
Equations for Past Year Drug Demand
First Stage: Second Stage:
WLS for 1984 Probits for 1988
Marijuana Use Cocaine Use
0) Í2a) Í2b)
Constant 0.422a 0.108b 0.177
(0.066) (0.054) (0.200)
Marijuana Use (in 1984) 0.292a 0.226
(0.074) (0.176)
Age -0.006a -0.0017 -0.0022
(0.002) (0.0012) (0.0015)
Education -0.001 -0.0028b -0.0028b
(0.002) (0.0011) (0.0011)
Male 0.114a -0.006 0.002
(0.010) (0.009) (0.021)
Black -0.015 -0.011 -0.012c
(0.012) (0.007) (0.007)
Hispanic -0.088a 0.002 -0.004
(0.015) (0.011) (0.017)
Married -0.070a -0.020b -0.024c
(0.012) (0.008) (0.014)
Central City Residence 0.071a 0.0001 0.006
(0.017) (0.010) (0.015)
SMSA Residence 0.079a -0.006 -0.000003
(0.011) (0.009) (0.015)
Catholic Background 0.041a -0.001 0.002
(0.013) (0.007) (0.009)
No Religious Background 0.075a -0.025c -0.020
(0.028) (0.014) (0.018)
Earnings Past Year -0.0011a 0.0004c 0.0003
(in 1000s) (0.0003) (0.0002) (0.0003)
Cocaine Price -0.206 -0.184b -0.199b
(in 1000s) (0.163) (0.093) (0.091)
Both Parents Present -0.015 0.001 0.0004
Age 14 (0.011) (0.006) (0.006)
Alcoholic Parent 0.065a 0.007
(0.013) (0.013)
Beer Tax (in 1984) -0.019a 0.001
(0.007) (0.006)
Maximum Jail Time for Marijuana -0.0053
(in 1984) (0.0036)
No Fine for Marijuana 0.057a
(in 1984) (0.018)
Standard deviations are given in parentheses. In columns 2a and
2b, the constant indicates the probabil-
ity of cocaine use when all variables are set to zero, while
remaining coefficients represent the change in
probability of cocaine use for a unit change in the explanatory
variable while holding all other variables
constant at their mean values.
a. Significant at the 0.01 level.
b. Significant at the 0.05 level.
c. Significant at the 0.10 level.
This content downloaded from 130.166.3.5 on Tue, 18 Nov 2014
03:18:48 AM
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp
IS MARIJUANA A GATEWAY DRUG? 157
Of the other explanatory variables, those of greatest economic
relevance are earn-
ings and the price of cocaine. The results for these two
variables contradict, to a great
extent, evidence from Grossman et al. [1996a; 1996b] and
Saffer and Chaloupka [1996]
that marijuana is a normal good that is complementary with
cocaine. Though the
cocaine price does carry a negative coefficient, its effect is
statistically insignificant.
Moreover, the effect of earnings is negative and significant. An
interpretation of these
results, though, must consider the construction of the sample.
As cocaine becomes
more expensive, some respondents who would otherwise have
initiated cocaine and
therefore been excluded from the sample may instead substitute
toward marijuana
rather than away from illegal drugs altogether, contributing to
the insignificance of
the cocaine price. The same may occur as earnings declines,
since the large expense of
cocaine per dose may imply a large income effect. It does not
necessarily follow that
marijuana and cocaine use are unrelated, nor that marijuana is
an inferior good, for
the general population that also includes cocaine users. The
only other surprising
result is the significantly higher likelihood of use for Catholics,
which again may be
an artifact of the sample selection procedure if Catholic drug
users are more inclined
to use marijuana than cocaine as a producer of euphoria. The
remaining explanatory
variables have the expected relationship with marijuana
consumption, and all are
significant besides educational attainment, black racial status,
and the presence of
both parents in the household at age fourteen.
Column 2a of Table 3 gives the results for equation (I1), the
second stage probit for
1988 cocaine demand. As previously discussed, past marijuana
use is identified through
the exclusion of both the two marijuana penalty variables and
the two alcohol-related
variables. The coefficients are reported in terms of the change
in probability of co-
caine use induced by a unit change in the explanatory variable
while holding all other
variables constant at their mean values, while the constant
represents the probabil-
ity of cocaine use when all variables equal zero. The crucial
result, of course, is the
statistically significant and extremely large positive effect of
past marijuana use. In
particular, past marijuana use raises the probability of
consuming cocaine by more
than 29 percentage points. This impact is clearly substantial,
dwarfing that of the
other explanatory variables, for realistic variations in their
values, by a factor of at
least ten. Not only is a strong gateway effect of marijuana on
cocaine apparent, there-
fore, but it is by far the most important factor in explaining
current cocaine demand.
The relevance of economic factors is shown by the fact that
besides earnings and
the price of cocaine, only three other exogenous variables in
column 2a are signifi-
cant. The coefficients of the earnings and price variables
indicate, in agreement with
findings of Grossman et al. [1996b] and Saffer and Chaloupka
[1996], that cocaine is
a normal good with a downward-sloping demand curve. The
magnitudes of these ef-
fects, however, are modest. An increase in earnings of one
standard deviation, or
$15,000, raises the probability of using cocaine by just over
half a percentage point,
which is almost identical to the impact of lowering the price of
cocaine by one stan-
dard deviation, or $30. The implied price elasticity of -0.40 is,
nonetheless, consis-
tent with that estimated in the studies mentioned above.
Meanwhile, the other sig-
nificant results indicate that four additional years of education,
marriage, and an
This content downloaded from 130.166.3.5 on Tue, 18 Nov 2014
03:18:48 AM
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp
158 EASTERN ECONOMIC JOURNAL
TABLE 4
Specification Tests for Cocaine Use Probits
Model (a) Model (b)
First Stage F-statistic for Excluded Instruments 12.84 6.25
(0.000) (0.002)
Overidentification Test x2-statistic 1.577 0.523
(0.816) (0.770)
Second Stage x2-statistic for Alcohol Variables - 0.83
(0.660)
Hausman Test t-statistic 0.231a 0.164
(0.060) (0.152)
Hausman Test for (a) vs (b) - 0.067
(0.140)
Models (a) and (b) correspond to columns 2a and 2b,
respectively, of Table 3. P-values are given in
parentheses beneath F and x2-statistics, while standard
deviations are given in parentheses beneath t-
statistics.
a. Significant at the .01 level.
upbringing that involves religion lowers the probability of using
cocaine by 1, 2, and
2.5 percentage points, respectively. Again, though, the most
notable characteristic of
the significant coefficients is that their magnitudes are trivial in
comparison with
that of past marijuana use.
Table 4 reports the results of various tests regarding the
specification of the IV
procedure. The test statistics in column a correspond to the
model of column 2a in
Table 3. In the top row, the joint F-statistic for the excluded
instruments Z^ verifies
that these variables are highly correlated with marijuana
demand, an essential con-
dition for minimizing the standard errors of the IV estimates.
Consequently, any
inconsistency in the IV estimates arising from a weak nonzero
correlation between
Z^ and ec should be low relative to that of OLS. Following
Bound et al. [1995], this F-
statistic also implies that the inherent small sample bias in the
IV estimates is only
about 1 IF, or 8 percent, of the bias arising from OLS
estimation.
The next row gives the statistic for a test of the validity of the
overidentifying
restrictions. If ZM is jointly correlated with ec and therefore
should in reality be in-
cluded in equation (I1), then the IV estimates of equation (I1)
are inconsistent. Lee
[1991] illustrates how a chi-square test statistic for the
overidentifying restrictions,
with degrees of freedom equal to the number of excluded
instruments, can be ob-
tained as a by-product of the IV regression methodology
because, as Blundell and
Smith [1989] show, the estimation procedure is a minimum chi-
square method. The
joint hypothesis that the excluded instruments neither belong in
the second stage
equation (I1) nor are correlated with the second stage residuals
ec cannot be rejected
at standard significance levels. More precisely, the extremely
high p-value provides
evidence that any correlation between Zw and ec is quite weak.
This content downloaded from 130.166.3.5 on Tue, 18 Nov 2014
03:18:48 AM
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp
IS MARIJUANA A GATEWAY DRUG? 159
The remaining statistic in column a of Table 4, appearing in the
fourth row, is for
a test of the exogeneity of past marijuana use in equation (I1).
As Smith and Blundell
[1986] show, the t-statistic for the coefficient of the first stage
residual em, b3, in equa-
tion (I1) provides an exogeneity test that is analogous to the
standard Hausman test
for exogeneity [Hausman, 1978]. Since the IV procedure is
correctly specified, as the
F and overidentification tests verify, any difference in the IV
and OLS estimates of bv
the gateway effect, arises because a nonzero correlation
between Mw and ec affects
the OLS but not the IV estimate. The exogeneity test statistic
measures the magni-
tude of this difference and thus indicates an OLS estimate of
0.061. Since the IV
estimate is significantly larger than the OLS estimate, the latter
must exhibit down-
ward bias. This bias has two potential causes: observable
factors that in reality affect
cocaine use in part through marijuana use, and unobservable
factors that increase
past marijuana demand while decreasing current cocaine
demand.
To disentangle these two sources of bias, I evaluate the IV
estimates of the co-
caine demand equation (I1) at mean values of the explanatory
variables for marijuana
users and nonusers (not reported here) while holding marijuana
use constant and
take the difference in predicted cocaine use between users and
nonusers. I then do
the same for the OLS estimates of equation (I1) (also not
reported here). The differ-
ence between these two quantities reveals that only 1.5
percentage points of the dis-
crepancy between the IV and OLS estimates of the gateway
effect represent effects of
exogenous explanatory variables that in reality work through
past marijuana use,
but are incorrectly attributed by OLS to the variables
themselves. Unobserved het-
erogeneity must account for the remainder of the difference
between the IV and OLS
coefficients. More precisely, unobserved factors make
marijuana users 21.6 percent-
age points less likely than nonusers to consume cocaine. Unlike
OLS, the IV method-
ology is able to separate this unobserved heterogeneity from the
true causal effect of
marijuana use. This finding contradicts the conventional
wisdom that the gateway
effect is an artifact of unobserved variables that make both
marijuana and cocaine
consumption more likely, suggesting instead that unobserved
substitutability of mari-
juana and cocaine use masks an even greater effect of marijuana
use than the OLS
estimate of the gateway effect indicates. This result is not
inconsistent with
intertemporal complementarity of marijuana and cocaine use. It
simply implies that
marijuana users have actively chosen marijuana over cocaine as
a producer of eupho-
ria. The unobserved reasons for this choice make them,
ceterisparibus, less likely to
progress to cocaine use than others who have never used
cocaine, even though these
others may have been more likely to avoid illegal drugs
altogether. Ironically, mari-
juana users are subsequently more likely to use cocaine because
of the substantial
effect of marijuana use itself.
The variables in Z^ most likely to belong in the second stage
equation (I1) are the
alcoholic parent indicator and the beer tax. To further evaluate
the validity of exclud-
ing these two variables, I directly compare the specification
discussed so far to an
alternative specification in which these variables are included in
equation (I1). Col-
umn 2b of Table 3 shows the estimates of this alternative
model. Not surprisingly, the
effects of the exogenous variables are quite similar across the
two IV equations. In
This content downloaded from 130.166.3.5 on Tue, 18 Nov 2014
03:18:48 AM
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp
160 EASTERN ECONOMIC JOURNAL
addition, the estimated gateway effect in column 2b is much
closer to that of column
2a than that of OLS. Because the standard error is more than
twice as large as that in
2a, though, the estimate in 2b is not significantly different from
zero and hence yields
a much different implication than does the estimate in 2a.
Column b of Table 4 displays the results of the relevant
specification tests for the
model presented in column 2b of Table 3, allowing investigation
of the sources of the
variation between the two IV estimates of the gateway effect.
The top two rows verify
that this alternative model is also validly specified. The relative
magnitudes of the F-
statistics in columns a and b imply that the gateway estimate in
column 2b of Table 3
will exhibit greater small sample bias than that in column 2a. It
is thus expected that,
as Table 3 indicates, the estimate in column 2b is closer to the
OLS estimate than is
that in column 2a. Meanwhile, the third row shows that the two
alcohol-related vari-
ables are jointly insignificant in the cocaine demand equation,
which is not surprising
given that neither individually approaches significance in Table
3. This result pro-
vides explicit evidence that the two alcohol variables are validly
excluded from the
cocaine demand equation, which supports the more general
conclusion from the col-
umn a overidentification test statistic that the full exclusion
restriction is valid. Fi-
nally, the bottom two rows report the statistics for the
exogeneity tests that compare
the gateway coefficient in this model to those of the OLS and
column a models, re-
spectively. Though the model a estimate is significantly
different from the OLS esti-
mate, the estimate of this model is not significantly different
from those of either
column a or OLS because of the large standard error.
The combined results of the specification tests indicate that the
primary conse-
quence of the exclusion of the two alcohol-related variables
from the cocaine demand
equation is an increase in efficiency of the IV estimate of the
gateway effect. Since
these variables are highly related to past marijuana consumption
but not separately
related to current cocaine consumption, their exclusion does not
alter the magnitude
of the estimate of the gateway effect, but does provide the
additional explanatory
power necessary to reduce the standard errors enough to
produce statistical signifi-
cance. Furthermore, the evidence that alcohol use leads to
cocaine use only through
its strong complementarity with marijuana use is consistent with
the hypothesis that
a separate intertemporal link from alcohol to marijuana
precedes the one from mari-
juana to cocaine that is shown here.
CONCLUSION
This study has found evidence of a gateway from marijuana to
cocaine that takes
place at later ages than were previously thought relevant.
Structural estimates ac-
counting for unobserved heterogeneity that affects both
marijuana and cocaine de-
mand indicate that past marijuana use increases the probability
of current cocaine
use by twenty-nine percentage points. This effect is nearly three
times as large as the
one-in-ten increase that Kleiman [1992] cites as warranting a
considerable expansion
in efforts to control marijuana use. To put the magnitude of this
result in perspective,
preventing past marijuana use decreases the likelihood of
cocaine initiation by an
amount that is almost thirteen times greater than that brought
about by a doubling
This content downloaded from 130.166.3.5 on Tue, 18 Nov 2014
03:18:48 AM
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp
IS MARIJUANA A GATEWAY DRUG? 161
of the average cocaine price, which any feasible enforcement
effort is unlikely to ac-
complish [Kleiman, 1992]. In order to most effectively deter
cocaine use, therefore,
some resources devoted to raising prices, which is the
predominant focus of present
U.S. drug policy, should be redirected towards the prevention of
marijuana initiation
by adolescents and young adults.
As a caveat, the estimate of the gateway effect obtained here
suffers from several
potential deficiencies as a result of data limitations. First,
current and past drug use
are crudely measured with a longtime interval between the two
periods. Consequently,
questions remain regarding the extent and persistence of
marijuana use necessary to
bring about cocaine use and the length of time between
marijuana and cocaine initia-
tion. Second, the gateway effect may be less pronounced for
younger cocaine users
who were excluded from the sample employed here. Earlier
cocaine use may reflect a
stronger inclination towards cocaine that makes it less likely to
be preceded by mari-
juana use. In addition, the unobserved factors found here to bias
the OLS estimate
towards zero may be an artifact of the substitution away from
cocaine by marijuana
users who have not tried cocaine by this relatively late age and
may thus not be
representative of unobservables for younger cohorts.
Conversely, to the extent that
late cocaine initiation reflects a lower propensity for
intoxication, this estimate of the
gateway effect may instead be conservative. Third, cohort
effects may make this esti-
mate inapplicable for the comparable age group today. In
particular, the demand for
illegal drugs has apparently shifted down in the last decade in
response to attitudinal
changes [SAMHSA, 1996].
Even conditional on the generalizability of the estimate
obtained here, policy im-
plications depend crucially on the contemporaneous relationship
between marijuana
and alcohol use. If these drugs are indeed complements, as
indicated here and in
Saffer and Chaloupka [1996], then policy should clearly aim to
restrict youth mari-
juana use. On the other hand, if these drugs are in fact
substitutes, as several previ-
ously cited studies have found, then restrictive marijuana policy
involves a tradeoff
between reducing future cocaine demand and increasing current
alcohol demand.
The latter is problematic because alcohol intoxication most
likely involves greater
health, accident and crime risks than marijuana intoxication.
Similarly, policy impli-
cations depend on the nature of the unobserved factors found
here to be responsible
for the inconsistency in the OLS estimates, since they reflect a
component of the
contemporaneous relationship between marijuana and cocaine.
Namely, does the
negative correlation between unobservables affecting marijuana
and cocaine imply
that restrictive marijuana policy would push teenagers and
young adults to substi-
tute cocaine for marijuana at an earlier age rather than simply
block the gateway to
cocaine use?
To further clarify policy goals, future research should attempt
to identify the fun-
damental relationships underlying the gateway from marijuana
to cocaine. In par-
ticular, empirical analysis should seek to establish the relative
importance of mari-
juana addiction, the contemporaneous relationship between
marijuana and cocaine,
and the direct intertemporal effect that exists because both
drugs produce euphoria.
For instance, Pacula [1997] reports evidence of both addictive
marijuana and strong
contemporaneous complementarity between alcohol and
marijuana, but fails to find a
This content downloaded from 130.166.3.5 on Tue, 18 Nov 2014
03:18:48 AM
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp
162 EASTERN ECONOMIC JOURNAL
separate direct gateway from alcohol to marijuana.12
Comparable information for the
gateway from marijuana to cocaine can delineate the role that
reducing the persis-
tence over time of marijuana use must play in the effort to avert
the progression from
marijuana to cocaine use.
NOTES
I am grateñil to Frank Chaloupka and Mike Grossman of the
National Bureau of Economic Research
for graciously providing the cocaine price data used herein, the
Bureau of Labor Statistics for allow-
ing my use of the restricted NLSY geocode data, and two
anonymous referees and the editor for
suggestions that substantially improved the paper.
1. Even though Mt_h is a predetermined variable in equation
(1), this issue is empirically relevant
because many determinants of marijuana and cocaine use are
either time-invariant or highly corre-
lated over time, as is marijuana consumption if it is indeed
addictive.
2. For this reason, though I label equation (2) as a marijuana
demand equation and later analyze it as
such, it is more strictly interpreted as an instrumenting
equation. It should be noted, though, that
the use of lagged rather than current values of X does not
change the estimates of equation (2) much.
3. In addition, data constraints dictate the use of binary
measures of drug consumption, as discussed in
the following section.
4. Lack of information on lifetime cocaine use in 1980 prevents
the estimation of the relationship be-
tween 19S0 marijuana use and 19S4 cocaine use.
5. All monetary variables are converted to 1982-84 equivalents
using the CPI for all urban consumers.
6. As explained in detail in Grossman et al. [1996b], a
regression of the price of the transaction on its
weight and purity and a set of city and year dummies is run and
then used to predict a standardized
price for each city and year. This procedure is similar to the
ones developed by Caulkins [1994] and
Saffer and Chaloupka [1996]. These standardized prices were
generously supplied to me by Frank
Chaloupka and Mike Grossman of NBER. I then created a past
year price by taking a weighted
average of the 1987 and 1988 prices for each city based on the
interview month. Since a price esti-
mate exists for at least one city in each state, each county of
residence in the NLSY is assigned the
price from the city within the same state that is geographically
closest. Although the matching pro-
cess introduces measurement error that most likely biases the
estimates of the price elasticity of
marijuana and cocaine demand towards zero, the imputed prices
should be reasonably accurate for
the large majority of the sample that resides in urban areas.
7. The retail price of marijuana would be the ideal instrumental
variable for marijuana use. However,
because DEA agents do not focus on apprehending marijuana
dealers, the number of marijuana
purchases recorded in the DEA database that generate the
cocaine price estimates used here is
insufficient to estimate a reliable price series for marijuana.
8. The maximum prison term yields almost identical results to
the midpoint of the range of the poten-
tial prison term, or any other weighted average of the minimum
and maximum prison sentence,
because the minimum prison term exceeds zero in only two
states, Arizona (mandatory 1.5 years)
and West Virginia (range from 3 to 6 months). Note that beyond
the two included variables, other
measures of state-level marijuana penalties, including minimum
and maximum fines for possession
and an indicator of decriminalization, are not significantly
related to marijuana use.
9. The reasons for excluding the remaining 5,407 respondents
from the original NLSY cohort are as
follows. First, the 1,280 members of the military sample are not
included, though in any event 1,079
of these respondents are dropped from the NLSY after 1984 and
accordingly the necessary informa-
tion for inclusion exists for only 113 people out of the original
1,280. An additional 1,320 respondents
are not interviewed in one of the two years. The sample next
omits the 397 individuals who are in the
military (although drug price and penalty variables could not be
matched for this group in any case
because states of residence are not recorded for military
respondents) and the 190 respondents who
are incarcerated at the time of either interview, since these
people may not have the same opportu-
nity to consume illegal drugs as others. Another 120 individuals
live outside the United States in
This content downloaded from 130.166.3.5 on Tue, 18 Nov 2014
03:18:48 AM
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp
IS MARIJUANA A GATEWAY DRUG? 163
either 19S4 or 1988, while an additional 1,484 respondents have
consumed cocaine by the 1984
interview. The remaining exclusions occur because values are
missing for one of the two drug use
variables in 162 cases and for an explanatory variable in 454
instances.
10. A separate potential source of bias is the refusal of drug
users to answer the survey questions on drug
use. Refusal bias seems improbable, though, because missing
values for either 19S4 marijuana or
19SS cocaine use are responsible for the exclusion of only 162
individuals. Moreover, although 156 of
these respondents report marijuana use but not cocaine use, the
prevalence of marijuana use among
these respondents, 17.9 percent, is slightly lower than the
prevalence of 24.6 percent among sample
respondents.
11. To maintain unbiasedness under this scenario,
underreporters must be less likely to use marijuana
than others, rather than equally likely as in the case in which
cocaine use is underreported only in
1988.
12. Though in her analysis marijuana plays the role of cocaine
here, Pacula [1997] does not eliminate
previous users of marijuana from her sample and therefore must
consider marijuana addiction as an
additional element of the intertemporal relationship between
alcohol and marijuana.
REFERENCES
Becker, G. and Murphy, K. A Theory of Rational Addiction.
Journal of Political Economy, August 1988,
675-700.
Beer Institute. Brewer's Almanac. Washington, D.C.: U.S.
Brewer's Association, 1995.
Blundell, R. and Smith, R. Estimation in a Class of
Simultaneous Equation Limited Dependent Vari-
able Models. Review of Economic Studies, January 1989, 37-57.
Bound, J., Jaegar, D., and Baker, R. Problems With
Instrumental Variables Estimation When the
Correlation Between the Instruments and the Endogenous
Explanatory Variable is Weak. Jour-
nal of the American Statistical Association, June 1995, 443-50.
Cadoret, R. Genetic and Environmental Factors in Initiation of
Drug Abuse and the Transition to Abuse,
in Vulnerability to Drug Abuse, edited by M. Glantz and R.
Pickens. Washington, D.C.: American
Psychological Association, 1992.
Caulkins, J. Developing Price Series for Cocaine. Santa Monica,
CA: RAND, 1994.
Center for Human Resource Research. NLS User's Guide.
Columbus, OH: Ohio State University,
1995.
Chaloupka, F. Rational Addictive Behavior and Cigarette
Smokmg. Journal of Political Economy, Au-
gust 1991, 722-742.
Chaloupka, F. and Laixuthai, A. Do Youths Substitute Alcohol
and Marijuana.'' borne üiconometnc
Evidence. NBER Working Paper No. 4662, February 1994.
DeSimone, J. Illegal Drug Use and Labor Supply. Unpublished
manuscript, Yale University, November
1997.
DiNardo, J. and Lemieux, T. Alcohol, Marijuana, and American
Youth: The Unintended Effects of
Government Regulation. NBER Working Paper No. 4212,
November 1992.
Grossman, M., Chaloupka, F., and Brown, C. The Demand for
Marijuana by Young Adults: A Katio-
nal Addiction Approach. Unpublished manuscript, National
Bureau of Economic Research, April
1996a.
. The Demand for Cocaine by Young Adults: A Rational
Addiction Approach. NBER Working
Paper No. 5713, August 1996b.
Gujarati, D. Basic Econometrics. New York: McGraw-Hill,
1995.
Hausman, J. Specification Tests in Econometrics. Econometrica,
November 1978, 1251-71.
Hoyt, G. and Chaloupka, F. Effect of Survey Conditions on
Selt-Keported Substance use. contempo-
rary Economic Policy, July 1994, 109-21.
Johnston, L., O'Malley, P. and Bachman, J. Illicit Drug Use,
Smoking ana Drinking ay Americas
High School Students, College Students, and Young Adults.
Washington, D.C.: U.S. Department
of Health and Human Services, 1988.
Kandel, D. and Yamaguchi, K. From Beer to Crack:
Developmental Patterns of Drug Involvement.
American Journal of Public Health, June 1993, 851-55.
This content downloaded from 130.166.3.5 on Tue, 18 Nov 2014
03:18:48 AM
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp
164 EASTERN ECONOMIC JOURNAL
Kenkel, D. and Ribar, D. Alcohol Consumption and Young
Adults* Socioeconomic Status. Brookings
Papers on Economic Activity: Microeconomics, 1994, 119-61.
Kleiman, M. Against Excess: Drug Policy for Results. New
York: Basic Books, 1992.
Lee, L. Amemiya's Generalized Least Squares and Tests of
Overidentification in Simultaneous Equation
Models with Qualitative or Limited Dependent Variables.
Center for Economic Research Discus-
sion Paper No. 262, University of Minnesota, May 1991.
Mensch, B. and Kandel, D. Underreporting of Substance Use in
a National Longitudinal Youth Cohort.
Public Opinion Quarterly, Spring 1988, 100-24.
Merikangas, K., Rounsaville, B., and Prusoff, B. Familial
Factors in Vulnerability to Substance Abuse,
in Vulnerability to Drug Abuse, edited by M. Glantz and R.
Pickens. Washington, D.C.: American
Psvcholocical Association. 1992.
Mills, C. and Noyes, H. Patterns and Correlates of Initial and
Subsequent Drug Use Among Adoles-
cents. Journal of Consulting and Clinical Psychology, April
1984, 231-43.
Model, K. The Effect of Marijuana Decriminalization on
Hospital Emergency Room Drug Episodes: 1975-
1978. Journal of the American Statistical Association,
September 1993, 737-47.
Newcomb, M. and Bentler, P. Cocaine Use Among Adolescents:
Longitudinal Associations with Social
Context, Psychopathology, and Use of Other Substances.
Addictive Behaviors, November 1986,
263-73.
O'Donnell, J. and Clayton, R. The Stepping-Stone Hypothesis -
Marijuana, Heroin and Causality.
Chemical Dependencies, March 1982, 229-41.
Pacula, R. Adolescent Alcohol and Marijuana Consumption: Is
There Really a Gateway Effect? Unpub-
lished manuscript, University of San Diego, 1997.
Saffer, H. and Chaloupka, F. The Demand for Illicit Drugs.
Unpublished manuscript, National Bureau
of Economic Research, 1996.
Sickles, R. and Taubman, P. Who Uses Illegal Drugs? American
Economic Review, May 1991, 248-51.
Smith, R. and Blundell, R. An Exogeneity Test for a
Simultaneous Equation Tobit Model with an
Application to Labor Supply. Econometrica, May 1986, 679-85.
Stigler, G. and Becker, G. De Gustibus Non Est Disputandum.
American Economic Review, March
1977, 76-90.
Substance Abuse and Mental Health Services Administration
(SAMHSA). National Household
Survey on Drug Abuse: Population Estimates 1995. Rockville,
MD: U.S. Department of Health and
Human Services, 1996.
Yamaguchi, K. and Kandel, D. Patterns of Drug Use from
Adolescence to Young Adulthood: 111. Predic-
tors of Progression. American Journal of Public Health, July
1984, 673-81.
This content downloaded from 130.166.3.5 on Tue, 18 Nov 2014
03:18:48 AM
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jspArticle
Contentsp. 149p. 150p. 151p. 152p. 153p. 154p. 155p. 156p.
157p. 158p. 159p. 160p. 161p. 162p. 163p. 164Issue Table of
ContentsEastern Economic Journal, Vol. 24, No. 2 (Spring,
1998), pp. 127-251Front MatterMonetary Rules [pp. 127-
136]New Deal Agricultural Appropriations: A Political
Influence [pp. 137-148]Is Marijuana a Gateway Drug? [pp. 149-
164]Does the Minimum Wage Affect Employment in Mexico?
[pp. 165-180]Coping Rationally with Unpreferred Preferences
[pp. 181-194]Does the Federal Reserve Lexicographically Order
Its Policy Objectives? [pp. 195-206]Revisiting Long-Run
Industry Supply [pp. 207-215]Islamic and Neo-Confucian
Perspectives on the New Traditional Economy [pp. 217-
227]Other Things EqualSmall Worlds, or, the Preposterousness
of Closed Economy Macro [pp. 229-232]Book ReviewsReview:
untitled [pp. 233-235]Review: untitled [pp. 235-238]Review:
untitled [pp. 238-240]Review: untitled [pp. 240-242]Review:
untitled [pp. 242-244]Review: untitled [pp. 244-247]Review:
untitled [pp. 247-249]Review: untitled [pp. 250-251]Back
Matter
The University of Chicago
The Booth School of Business of the University of Chicago
The University of Chicago Law School
Medical Marijuana Laws, Traffic Fatalities, and Alcohol
Consumption
Author(s): D. Mark Anderson, Benjamin Hansen, and Daniel I.
Rees
Source: Journal of Law and Economics, Vol. 56, No. 2 (May
2013), pp. 333-369
Published by: The University of Chicago Press for The Booth
School of Business of the University of
Chicago and The University of Chicago Law School
Stable URL: http://www.jstor.org/stable/10.1086/668812 .
Accessed: 18/11/2014 03:00
Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the
Terms & Conditions of Use, available at .
http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp
.
JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars,
researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide
range of
content in a trusted digital archive. We use information
technology and tools to increase productivity and facilitate new
forms
of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please
contact [email protected]
.
The University of Chicago Press, The University of Chicago,
The Booth School of Business of the University of
Chicago, The University of Chicago Law School are
collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend
access to Journal of Law and Economics.
http://www.jstor.org
This content downloaded from 130.166.3.5 on Tue, 18 Nov 2014
03:00:05 AM
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
http://www.jstor.org/action/showPublisher?publisherCode=ucpr
ess
http://www.jstor.org/action/showPublisher?publisherCode=chica
gobooth
http://www.jstor.org/action/showPublisher?publisherCode=chica
gobooth
http://www.jstor.org/action/showPublisher?publisherCode=chica
golaw
http://www.jstor.org/stable/10.1086/668812?origin=JSTOR-pdf
http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp
http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp
333
[Journal of Law and Economics, vol. 56 (May 2013)]
� 2013 by The University of Chicago. All rights reserved.
0022-2186/2013/5602-0011$10.00
Medical Marijuana Laws, Traffic Fatalities,
and Alcohol Consumption
D. Mark Anderson Montana State University
Benjamin Hansen University of Oregon
Daniel I. Rees University of Colorado Denver
Abstract
To date, 19 states have passed medical marijuana laws, yet very
little is known
about their effects. The current study examines the relationship
between the
legalization of medical marijuana and traffic fatalities, the
leading cause of death
among Americans ages 5–34. The first full year after coming
into effect, legal-
ization is associated with an 8–11 percent decrease in traffic
fatalities. The impact
of legalization on traffic fatalities involving alcohol is larger
and estimated with
more precision than its impact on traffic fatalities that do not
involve alcohol.
Legalization is also associated with sharp decreases in the price
of marijuana
and alcohol consumption, which suggests that marijuana and
alcohol are sub-
stitutes. Because alternative mechanisms cannot be ruled out,
the negative re-
lationship between legalization and alcohol-related traffic
fatalities does not
necessarily imply that driving under the influence of marijuana
is safer than
driving under the influence of alcohol.
1. Introduction
Medical marijuana laws (MMLs) remove state-level penalties
for using, pos-
sessing, and cultivating medical marijuana. Patients are required
to obtain ap-
proval or certification from a doctor, and doctors who
recommend marijuana
to their patients are immune from prosecution. Medical
marijuana laws allow
patients to designate caregivers who can obtain marijuana on
their behalf.
We would like to thank Dean Anderson, Brian Cadena,
Christopher Carpenter, Chad Cotti, Ben-
jamin Crost, Scott Cunningham, Brian Duncan, Andrew
Friedson, Darren Grant, Mike Hanlon,
Rosalie Pacula, Henri Pellerin, Claus Pörtner, Randy Rucker,
Doug Young, and seminar participants
at Clemson University, Colorado State University, Cornell
University, and the National Bureau of
Economics and Research Health Economics Program Meeting in
April 2012 for comments and
suggestions.
This content downloaded from 130.166.3.5 on Tue, 18 Nov 2014
03:00:05 AM
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp
334 The Journal of LAW & ECONOMICS
On May 2, 2013, Maryland became the nineteenth state, along
with the District
of Columbia, to enact an MML. More than a dozen state
legislatures, including
those of Illinois, New York, and Pennsylvania, have recently
considered medical
marijuana bills. If these bills are eventually signed into law, the
majority of
Americans will live in states that permit the use of medical
marijuana.
Opponents of medical marijuana tend to focus on the social
issues surrounding
substance use. They argue that marijuana is addictive, serves as
a gateway drug,
has little medicinal value, and leads to criminal activity (Adams
2008; Blankstein
2010). Proponents argue that marijuana is both efficacious and
safe and can be
used to treat the side effects of chemotherapy as well as the
symptoms of AIDS,
multiple sclerosis, epilepsy, glaucoma, and other serious
illnesses. They cite clin-
ical research showing that marijuana relieves chronic pain,
nausea, muscle
spasms, and appetite loss (Eddy 2010; Marmor 1998; Watson,
Benson, and Joy
2000) and note that neither the link between the use of medical
marijuana and
the use of other substances nor the link between medical
marijuana and criminal
activity has been substantiated (Belville 2011; Corry et al.
2009; Hoeffel 2011).
This study begins by using price data collected from back issues
of High Times,
the leading cannabis-related magazine in the United States, to
explore the effects
of MMLs on the market for marijuana. Our results are
consistent with anecdotal
evidence that MMLs have led to a substantial increase in the
supply of high-
grade marijuana (Montgomery 2010). In contrast, the impact of
MMLs on the
market for low-quality marijuana appears to be modest.
Next, we turn our attention to MMLs and traffic fatalities, the
primary re-
lationship of interest. Traffic fatalities are the leading cause of
death among
Americans ages 5–34.1 To our knowledge, there has been no
previous examination
of this relationship. Data on traffic fatalities at the state level
are obtained from
the Fatality Analysis Reporting System (FARS) for the years
1990–2010. Fourteen
states and the District of Columbia enacted an MML during this
period. The
FARS information includes the time of day the traffic fatality
occurred, the day
of the week it occurred, and whether alcohol was involved.
Using this infor-
mation, we contribute to the long-standing debate on whether
marijuana and
alcohol are substitutes or complements.
The first full year after coming into effect, the legalization of
medical marijuana
is associated with an 8–11 percent decrease in traffic fatalities.
However, the
effect of MMLs on traffic fatalities involving alcohol is larger
and estimated with
more precision than the effect of MMLs on traffic fatalities that
do not involve
alcohol. In addition, we find that the estimated effects of MMLs
on fatalities at
night and on weekends (when the level of alcohol consumption
increases) are
larger, and are more precise, than the estimated effects of
MMLs on fatalities
during the day and on weekdays.
1 These 2010 data on leading causes of fatalities are from the
Centers for Disease Control and
Prevention’s Web-Based Injury Statistics Query and Reporting
System (http://www.cdc.gov/injury/
wisqars).
This content downloaded from 130.166.3.5 on Tue, 18 Nov 2014
03:00:05 AM
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
http://www.cdc.gov/injury/wisqars
http://www.cdc.gov/injury/wisqars
http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp
Medical Marijuana Laws 335
Finally, the relationship between MMLs and more direct
measures of alcohol
consumption is examined. Using individual-level data from the
Behavioral Risk
Factor Surveillance System (BRFSS) for the period 1993–2010,
we find that
MMLs are associated with decreases in the probability of
having consumed
alcohol in the past month, binge drinking, and the number of
drinks consumed.
We conclude that alcohol is the likely mechanism through
which the legali-
zation of medical marijuana reduces traffic fatalities. However,
this conclusion
does not necessarily imply that driving under the influence of
marijuana is safer
than driving under the influence of alcohol. Alcohol is often
consumed in res-
taurants and bars, while many states prohibit the use of medical
marijuana in
public. If marijuana consumption typically takes place at home
or other private
locations, then legalization could reduce traffic fatalities simply
because mari-
juana users are less likely to drive while impaired.
2. Background
2.1. A Brief History of Medical Marijuana
Marijuana was introduced in the United States in the early
1600s by Jamestown
settlers who used the plant in hemp production; hemp
cultivation remained a
prominent industry until the mid-1800s (Deitch 2003). During
the census of
1850, the United States recorded more than 8,000 cannabis
plantations of at
least 2,000 acres (Cannabis Campaigners Guide 2011).
Throughout this period,
marijuana was commonly used by physicians and pharmacists to
treat a broad
spectrum of ailments (Pacula et al. 2002). From 1850 to 1942,
marijuana was
included in the United States Pharmacopoeia, the official list of
recognized me-
dicinal drugs (Bilz 1992).
In 1913, California passed the first marijuana prohibition law
aimed at rec-
reational use (Gieringer 1999); by 1936, the remaining 47 states
had followed
suit (Eddy 2010). In 1937, the Marihuana Tax Act (Pub. L. No.
75-238, ch. 553,
50 Stat. 551 [1937]) effectively discontinued the use of
marijuana for medicinal
purposes (Bilz 1992), and marijuana was classified as a
Schedule I drug in 1970.2
According to the Controlled Substances Act, a Schedule I drug
must have a
“high potential for abuse” and “no currently accepted medical
use in treatment
in the United States” (Eddy 2010, p. 3).
In 1996, California passed the Compassionate Use Act, which
removed crim-
inal penalties for using, possessing, and cultivating medical
marijuana. It also
provided immunity from prosecution to physicians who
recommended the use
of medical marijuana to their patients. Before 1996, a number of
states allowed
doctors to prescribe marijuana, but this had little practical
effect because of
2 The Marihuana Tax Act imposed a registration tax and
required extensive record keeping and
thus increased the cost of prescribing marijuana as compared to
other drugs (Bilz 1992).
This content downloaded from 130.166.3.5 on Tue, 18 Nov 2014
03:00:05 AM
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp
336 The Journal of LAW & ECONOMICS
Table 1
Medical Marijuana Laws, 1990–2010
State Effective Date
Alaska March 4, 1999
California November 6, 1996
Colorado June 1, 2001
District of Columbia July 27, 2010
Hawaii December 28, 2000
Maine December 22, 1999
Michigan December 4, 2008
Montana November 2, 2004
Nevada October 1, 2001
New Jersey October 1, 2010
New Mexico July 1, 2007
Oregon December 3, 1998
Rhode Island January 3, 2006
Vermont July 1, 2004
Washington November 3, 1998
Note. Arizona, Connecticut, Delaware, Maryland, and
Massachusetts legalized medical marijuana after 2010.
federal restrictions.3 Since 1996, 18 other states and the
District of Columbia
have joined California in legalizing the use of medical
marijuana (Table 1),
although it is still classified as a Schedule I drug by the federal
government.4
2.2. Studies on Substance Use and Driving
Laboratory studies have shown that cannabis use impairs
driving-related func-
tions such as distance perception, reaction time, and hand-eye
coordination
(Kelly, Darke, and Ross 2004; Sewell, Poling, and Sofuoglu
2009). However,
neither simulator nor driving-course studies provide consistent
evidence that
these impairments to driving-related functions lead to an
increased risk of col-
lision (Kelly, Darke, and Ross 2004; Sewell, Poling, and
Sofuoglu 2009), perhaps
because drivers under the influence of tetrahydrocannabinol
(THC), the primary
psychoactive substance in marijuana, engage in compensatory
behaviors such as
reducing their velocity, avoiding risky maneuvers, and
increasing their following
distances (Kelly, Darke, and Ross 2004; Sewell, Poling, and
Sofuoglu 2009).
Like marijuana, alcohol impairs driving-related functions such
as reaction time
and hand-eye coordination (Kelly, Darke, and Ross 2004;
Sewell, Poling, and
Sofuoglu 2009). Moreover, simulator and driving-course studies
provide une-
3 Federal regulations prohibit doctors from writing
prescriptions for marijuana. In addition, even
if a doctor were to illegally prescribe marijuana, it would be
against federal law for pharmacies to
distribute it. Doctors in states that have legalized medical
marijuana avoid violating federal law by
recommending marijuana to their patients rather than
prescribing its use.
4 Information on when medical marijuana laws (MMLs) were
passed was obtained from a Con-
gressional Research Services Report by Eddy (2010). Although
the New Jersey medical marijuana
law went into effect on October 1, 2010, implementation has
been delayed (Brittain 2012). Coding
New Jersey as a state without medical marijuana in 2010 has no
appreciable impact on our results.
This content downloaded from 130.166.3.5 on Tue, 18 Nov 2014
03:00:05 AM
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp
Medical Marijuana Laws 337
quivocal evidence that alcohol consumption leads to an
increased risk of collision
(Kelly, Darke, and Ross 2004; Sewell, Poling, and Sofuoglu
2009). Even at low
doses, drivers under the influence of alcohol tend to
underestimate the degree
to which they are impaired (MacDonald et al. 2008; Marczinski,
Harrison, and
Fillmore 2008; Robbe and O’Hanlon 1993; Sewell, Poling, and
Sofuoglu 2009),
drive at faster speeds, and take more risks (Burian, Liguori, and
Robinson 2002;
Ronen et al. 2008; Sewell, Poling, and Sofuoglu 2009). When
used in conjunction
with marijuana, alcohol appears to have an “additive or even
multiplicative”
effect on driving-related functions (Sewell, Poling, and
Sofuoglu 2009, p. 186),
although chronic marijuana users may be less impaired by
alcohol than infre-
quent users (Jones and Stone 1970; Marks and MacAvoy 1989;
Wright and Terry
2002).5
2.3. The Relationship between Marijuana and Alcohol
Although THC has not been linked to an increased risk of
collision in simulator
and driving-course studies, MMLs could impact traffic fatalities
through the
consumption of alcohol. While a number of studies have found
evidence of
complementarity between marijuana and alcohol (Pacula 1998;
Farrelly et al.
1999; Williams et al. 2004), others lend support to the
hypothesis that marijuana
and alcohol are substitutes. For instance, Chaloupka and
Laixuthai (1997) and
Saffer and Chaloupka (1999) found that marijuana
decriminalization led to
decreased alcohol consumption, while DiNardo and Lemieux
(2001) found that
increases in the minimum legal drinking age were positively
associated with the
use of marijuana.
Two recent studies used a regression discontinuity approach to
examine the
effect of the minimum legal drinking age on marijuana use but
came to different
conclusions. Crost and Guerrero (2012) analyzed data from the
National Survey
on Drug Use and Health (NSDUH). They found that marijuana
use decreased
sharply at 21 years of age, evidence consistent with
substitutability between
alcohol and marijuana. In contrast, Yörük and Yörük (2011),
who drew on data
from the National Longitudinal Survey of Youth 1997
(NLSY97), concluded that
alcohol and marijuana were complements. However, these
authors appear to
have inadvertently conditioned on having used marijuana at
least once since the
last interview. When Crost and Rees (2013) applied Yörük and
Yörük’s (2011)
research design to the NLSY97 data without conditioning on
having used mar-
ijuana since the last interview, they found no evidence that
alcohol and marijuana
were complements.
5 A large body of research in epidemiology attempts to assess
the effects of substance use on the
basis of observed tetrahydrocannabinol and alcohol levels in the
blood of drivers who have been in
accidents. For marijuana, the results have been mixed, while the
likelihood of an accident occurring
clearly increases with blood alcohol concentration (BAC) levels
(Sewell, Poling, and Sofuoglu 2009).
This content downloaded from 130.166.3.5 on Tue, 18 Nov 2014
03:00:05 AM
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp
338 The Journal of LAW & ECONOMICS
3. Medical Marijuana Laws and the Marijuana Market
Medical marijuana laws should, in theory, increase both the
supply of mar-
ijuana and the demand for marijuana, unambiguously leading to
an increase in
consumption (Pacula et al. 2010). They afford suppliers some
protection against
prosecution and allow patients to buy medical marijuana
without fear of being
arrested or fined, which lowers the full cost of obtaining
marijuana.6 Because it
is prohibitively expensive for the government to ensure that all
medicinal mar-
ijuana ends up in the hands of registered patients (especially in
states that permit
home cultivation), diversion to nonpatients almost certainly
occurs.7
The NSDUH is the best source of information on marijuana
consumption by
adults living in the United States. However, the NSDUH does
not provide
individual-level data with state identifiers to researchers and
did not publish
state-level estimates of marijuana use prior to 1999.8 Because
five states (including
California, Oregon, and Washington) legalized medical
marijuana during the
period 1996–99, we turn to back issues of High Times magazine
in order to
gauge the impact of legalization on the marijuana market.
Begun in 1975, High
Times is published monthly and covers topics ranging from
marijuana cultivation
to politics. Each issue also contains a section entitled “Trans
High Market Quo-
tations” in which readers provide marijuana prices from across
the country. In
addition to price, a typical entry includes information about
where the marijuana
was purchased, its strain, and its quality.
We collected price information from High Times for the period
1990–2011.
Jacobson (2004), who collected information on the price of
marijuana from High
6 The majority of MMLs allow patients to register on the basis
of medical conditions that cannot
be objectively confirmed (for example, chronic pain and
nausea). In fact, chronic pain is the most
common medical condition among patients seeking treatment
(see Table A1). According to recent
Arizona registry data, only seven of 11,186 applications for
medical marijuana have been denied
approval. Sun (2010) described “quick-in, quick-out mills,”
where physicians provide recommen-
dations for a nominal fee. Cochran (2010) reported on doctors
providing medical marijuana rec-
ommendations to patients via brief Web interviews on Skype.
7 Aside from Washington, D.C., and New Jersey, all MMLs
enacted during the period 1990–2010
allowed for home cultivation, and eight of 15 allowed patients
or caregivers to cultivate collectively
(see Table A2). A recent investigation concluded that thousands
of pounds of medical marijuana
grown in Colorado are diverted annually to the recreational
market (Wirfs-Brock, Seaton, and
Sutherland 2010). Thurstone, Lieberman, and Schmiege (2011)
interviewed 80 adolescents (15–19
years of age) undergoing outpatient substance abuse treatment
in Denver. Thirty-nine of the 80
reported having obtained marijuana from someone with a
medical marijuana license. Florio (2011)
described the story of four eighth graders in Montana who
received marijuana-laced cookies from
a registered medical marijuana patient.
8 Using these estimates, Wall et al. (2011, p. 714) found that
rates of marijuana use among 12–
17-year-olds were higher in states that had legalized medical
marijuana than in states that had not,
but they noted that “in the years prior to MML passage, there
was already a higher prevalence of
use and lower perceptions of risk” in states that had legalized
medical marijuana. Using NSDUH
data for the years 2002–9, Harper, Strumpf, and Kaufman
(2012) found that legalization was associated
with a small reduction in the rate of marijuana use among 12–
17-year-olds. Using data for the period
1995–2002 from Denver, Los Angeles, Portland, San Diego, and
San Jose, Gorman and Huber (2007)
found little evidence that marijuana consumption increased
among adult arrestees as a result of
legalization.
This content downloaded from 130.166.3.5 on Tue, 18 Nov 2014
03:00:05 AM
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp
Medical Marijuana Laws 339
Table 2
Medical Marijuana Laws and the Price of High-Quality
Marijuana, 1990–2011
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5)
MML �.304**
(.037)
�.103�
(.058)
3 Years before MML .022
(.074)
2 Years before MML .003
(.075)
1 Year before MML �.037
(.076)
Year of law change �.117�
(.061)
�.059
(.069)
�.060
(.096)
1 Year after MML �.156**
(.044)
�.082
(.070)
�.084
(.097)
2 Years after MML �.203**
(.074)
�.110
(.082)
�.113
(.120)
3 Years after MML �.211**
(.062)
�.128
(.084)
�.130
(.118)
4 Years after MML �.387**
(.123)
�.283*
(.115)
�.286*
(.125)
5� Years after MML �.439**
(.048)
�.257*
(.116)
�.262�
(.145)
R2 .224 .310 .241 .315 .315
State-specific linear time trends No Yes No Yes Yes
Note. The dependent variable is equal to the natural log of the
median price of marijuana in state s and
year t. Standard errors, corrected for clustering at the state
level, are in parentheses. Year fixed effects, state
fixed effects, and state covariates are included in all
specifications. MML p medical marijuana law. N p
920.
� Statistically significant at the 10% level.
* Statistically significant at the 5% level.
** Statistically significant at the 1% level.
Times for the period 1975–2000, distinguished between high-
quality (a category
that included Californian and Hawaiian sinsemilla) and low-
quality (a category
that included commercial grade Colombian and Mexican weed)
marijuana.9
Following Jacobson (2004), we classified marijuana purchases
by quality and
calculated the median per-ounce price by state and year.10
Table 2 presents
9 The plant variety (that is, strain), which part of the plant is
used, the method of storage, and
cultivation techniques are all important determinants of quality
and potency (McLaren et al. 2008).
In recent decades, there has been a marked trend toward indoor
cultivation and higher potency in
the United States (McLaren et al. 2008). Jacobson (2004)
argued that, ideally, prices would be deflated
by a measure of potency. Unfortunately, information on potency
is not available in the High Times
data.
10 A total of 8,271 purchases were coded. Of these, 7,029 were
classified as high quality and 1,242
were classified as low quality. Prior to 2004, information on the
seller was occasionally included in
the “Trans High Market Quotations” section of High Times.
Although dispensaries were never men-
tioned, they are a relatively recent phenomenon. The number of
dispensaries in California expanded
rapidly after 2004 (Jacobson et al. 2011), and the number of
dispensaries in Colorado and Montana
expanded rapidly after 2008 (Smith 2011, 2012). We compared
High Times price data for 2011–12
with price data posted on the Internet by 84 dispensaries located
in seven states. In four states
(California, Michigan, Nevada, and Washington), the prices
charged by dispensaries were statistically
This content downloaded from 130.166.3.5 on Tue, 18 Nov 2014
03:00:05 AM
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp
340 The Journal of LAW & ECONOMICS
estimates of the following equation:
ln(Price of high-quality marijuana ) p b � b MML � X bst 0 1
st st 2 (1)
� v � w � � ,s t st
where s indexes states and t indexes years. The variable MMLst
indicates whether
medical marijuana was legal in state s and year t, and b1
represents the estimated
relationship between legalization and the per ounce price of
high-quality mar-
ijuana. The vector Xst includes controls for the mean age in
state s and year t,
the unemployment rate, per capita income, whether the state had
a marijuana
decriminalization law in place, and the beer tax. State fixed
effects, represented
by vs, control for time-invariant unobservable factors at the
state level; year fixed
effects, represented by wt, control for common shocks to the
price of high-quality
marijuana.11
The baseline estimate suggests that the supply response to
legalization is larger
than the demand response. In particular, legalization is
associated with a 26.2
percent ( ) decrease in the price of high-quality
marijuana.�.304e � 1 p �.262
When we include state-specific linear time trends, intended to
control for omitted
variables at the state level that evolve at a constant rate,
legalization is associated
with a 9.8 percent decrease in the price of high-quality
marijuana.
Lagging the MML indicator provides evidence that the effect of
legalization
on the price of high-quality marijuana is not immediate.
Controlling for state-
specific linear time trends, we see that the estimated
coefficients of the MML
indicator lagged 1–3 years are negative but not statistically
significant. There is
indistinguishable from the prices provided by High Times
readers. In Arizona, Colorado, and Oregon,
the prices charged by dispensaries were significantly lower than
the prices provided by High Times
readers; however, these differences were generally not large in
magnitude. The greatest difference
was in Colorado, where dispensaries, on average, charged 24.4
percent less per ounce ($72.80) than
the prices provided by High Times readers. In Arizona,
dispensaries, on average, charged 10.3 percent
less per ounce ($36.60) than the prices provided by High Times
readers; in Oregon, dispensaries, on
average, charged 14.9 percent less per ounce ($37.20) than the
prices provided by High Times readers
(for dispensary price data, see WeedMaps.com, Dispensaries
[http://www.legalmarijuanadispensary
.com]).
11 Standard errors are corrected for clustering at the state level
(Bertrand, Duflo, and Mullainathan
2004). Descriptive statistics are presented in Table A3. The
mean age in state s and year t was
calculated using census data. The data on beer taxes are from
Brewers Almanac (Beer Institute 1990–
2010). The unemployment and income data are from the Bureau
of Labor Statistics and the Bureau
of Economic Analysis, respectively. The data on
decriminalization laws are from Model (1993) and
Scott (2010). During the period under study, the
decriminalization indicator captures only two policy
changes: Nevada and Massachusetts decriminalized the use of
marijuana in 2001 and 2010, respec-
tively. The majority of decriminalization laws were passed prior
to 1990. Following Jacobson’s ap-
proach (2004), the estimates presented in Tables 2 and 3 are
unweighted. When the regressions are
weighted by the number of observations used to calculate the
median price and state-specific linear
time trends are included on the right-hand side, estimates of the
relationship between legalization
and price are smaller and less precise than those reported in
Tables 2 and 3. Nevertheless, they
continue to show that legalization is associated with a
statistically significant reduction in the price
of high-quality marijuana after 4 years. When the regressions
are weighted by the number of ob-
servations used to calculate the median price but state-specific
linear time trends are not included
on the right-hand side, estimates of the relationship between
legalization and price are similar to
those reported in Tables 2 and 3.
This content downloaded from 130.166.3.5 on Tue, 18 Nov 2014
03:00:05 AM
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
http://www.legalmarijuanadispensary.com
http://www.legalmarijuanadispensary.com
http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp
Medical Marijuana Laws 341
Table 3
Medical Marijuana Laws and the Price of Low-Quality
Marijuana, 1990–2011
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5)
MML �.096
(.105)
�.075
(.150)
3 Years before MML .135
(.197)
2 Years before MML .103
(.108)
1 Year before MML �.088
(.200)
Year of law change �.035
(.154)
�.056
(.193)
�.013
(.196)
1 Year after MML �.250�
(.146)
�.182
(.176)
�.106
(.136)
2 Years after MML �.058
(.176)
�.016
(.190)
.053
(.166)
3 Years after MML �.244*
(.098)
�.114
(.141)
�.028
(.138)
4 Years after MML .032
(.403)
.046
(.373)
.131
(.429)
5� Years after MML �.038
(.073)
.271
(.335)
.370
(.267)
R2 .720 .748 .723 .751 .753
State-specific linear time trends No Yes No Yes Yes
Note. The dependent variable is equal to the natural log of the
median price of marijuana in state s and
year t. Standard errors, corrected for clustering at the state
level, are in parentheses. Year fixed effects, state
fixed effects, and state covariates are included in all
specifications. MML p medical marijuana law. N p
483.
� Statistically significant at the 10% level.
* Statistically significant at the 5% level.
a statistically significant 24.6 percent reduction in the price of
high-quality mar-
ijuana in the fourth full year after legalization. This pattern of
results is consistent
with state registry data from Colorado, Montana, and Rhode
Island showing
that patient numbers increased slowly in the years immediately
after legalization.12
Adding leads to the model with state-specific linear time trends
produces no
evidence that legalization was systematically preceded by
changes in tastes or
policies related to the market for high-quality marijuana.
Estimates of the relationship between legalization and the price
of low-quality
marijuana are presented in Table 3. The majority of these
estimates are negative.
However, with two exceptions, they are statistically
insignificant. Given that much
of the medicinal crop is grown indoors under ultraviolet lights
and that high-
12 Table A1 presents registry information by state. Montana
legalized medical marijuana in No-
vember 2004. Two years later, only 287 patients were
registered; 7 years later, 30,036 patients were
registered. The number of registered patients in Colorado
increased from 5,051 in January 2009 to
128,698 in June 2011. Patient numbers also appear to be
growing rapidly in Arizona, which passed
the Arizona Medical Marijuana Act on November 2, 2010. A
total of 11,133 patient applications had
been approved as of August 29, 2011; 40,463 patient
applications had been approved by June 30,
2012.
This content downloaded from 130.166.3.5 on Tue, 18 Nov 2014
03:00:05 AM
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp
342 The Journal of LAW & ECONOMICS
potency and high-quality strains such as Northern Lights and
Super Silver Haze
are favored by medical marijuana cultivators, this imprecision is
not surprising.
4. Medical Marijuana Laws and Traffic Fatalities
The estimates discussed above suggest that legalization leads to
a substantial
decrease in the price of high-quality marijuana and, presumably,
a correspond-
ingly large increase in consumption.13 In this section, we test
whether the impact
of legalization extends to traffic fatalities.
4.1. Data on Traffic Fatalities
We use data from FARS for the period 1990–2010 to examine
the relationship
between MMLs and traffic fatalities. These data are collected
by the National
Highway Traffic Safety Administration and represent an annual
census of all
fatal injuries suffered in motor vehicle accidents in the United
States. Information
on the circumstances of each crash and the persons and vehicles
involved is
obtained from a variety of sources, including police crash
reports, driver licensing
files, vehicle registration files, state highway department data,
emergency medical
services records, medical examiners’ reports, toxicology
reports, and death certifi-
cates.
Table 4 presents descriptive statistics and definitions for our
outcome mea-
sures. The variable Fatalities Totalst is equal to the number of
traffic fatalities
per 100,000 people of state s in year t.14 The variables
Fatalities (BAC 1 0)st and
Fatalities (BAC ≥ .10)st allow us to examine the effects of
legalization by alcohol
involvement. The variable Fatalities (BAC 1 0)st is equal to the
number of traffic
fatalities per 100,000 people resulting from accidents in which
at least one driver
had a positive blood alcohol concentration (BAC). The variable
Fatalities (BAC
≥ .10)st is defined analogously, but at least one driver had to
have a BAC greater
than or equal to .10. The variable Fatalities (No Alcohol)st is
equal to the number
of fatalities per 100,000 people in which alcohol involvement
was not reported.15
13 If we assume, conservatively, that legalization has a
negligible impact on demand, then the
change in marijuana consumption is equal to the elasticity of
demand multiplied by the percentage
change in price. Only a handful of researchers have estimated
the price elasticity of demand for
marijuana. Using data on University of California, Los Angeles,
undergraduates, Nisbet and Vakil
(1972) estimated a price elasticity of demand between �1.01
and �1.51; using data from Monitoring
the Future on high school seniors, Pacula et al. (2001) estimated
a 30-day participation elasticity
between �.002 and �.69; using data from the Harvard College
Alcohol Study, Williams et al. (2004)
estimated a 30-day participation elasticity of �.24.
14 For population data, see National Cancer Institute, US
Population Data—1969–2011 (http://
seer.cancer.gov/popdata/index.html). According to Eisenberg
(2003), traffic fatalities in the Fatality
Analysis Reporting System (FARS) are measured with little to
no error. We experimented with scaling
traffic fatalities by the population of licensed drivers and by the
number of miles driven in state s
and year t rather than by the state population. These estimates,
which are similar in terms of magnitude
and precision to those presented here, are available on request.
15 The numerator for Fatalities (No Alcohol)st was determined
from two sources in FARS. First,
either all drivers involved had to have registered a BAC of zero
or, if BAC information was missing,
the police had to report that alcohol was not involved.
This content downloaded from 130.166.3.5 on Tue, 18 Nov 2014
03:00:05 AM
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
http://seer.cancer.gov/popdata/index.html
http://seer.cancer.gov/popdata/index.html
http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp
Medical Marijuana Laws 343
Table 4
Dependent Variables for the Fatality Analysis Reporting System
Analysis
Dependent Variable Mean Description
Fatalities Total 14.58 (5.05) Fatalities per 100,000 people
Fatalities (No Alcohol) 9.67 (3.45) Fatalities per 100,000
people with no indication of
alcohol involvement
Fatalities (BAC 1 0) 3.97 (1.74) Fatalities per 100,000 people
for which at least one
driver involved had a blood alcohol
concentration (BAC) 1 .00
Fatalities (BAC ≥ .10) 3.13 (1.43) Fatalities per 100,000 people
for which at least one
driver involved had a BAC 1 .10
Fatalities, 15–19 24.55 (9.75) Fatalities per 100,000 people 15–
19 years of age
Fatalities, 20–29 23.59 (8.41) Fatalities per 100,000 people 20–
29 years of age
Fatalities, 30–39 15.45 (6.49) Fatalities per 100,000 people 30–
39 years of age
Fatalities, 40–49 14.00 (5.63) Fatalities per 100,000 people 40–
49 years of age
Fatalities, 50–59 13.22 (4.93) Fatalities per 100,000 people 50–
59 years of age
Fatalities, 60� 17.39 (5.28) Fatalities per 100,000 people 60
years old and above
Fatalities Males 20.48 (7.15) Fatalities per 100,000 males
Fatalities Females 9.03 (3.29) Fatalities per 100,000 females
Fatalities Weekdays 8.32 (2.88) Fatalities per 100,000 people
on weekdays
Fatalities Weekends 6.22 (2.25) Fatalities per 100,000 people
on weekends
Fatalities Daytime 7.04 (2.59) Fatalities per 100,000 people
during the day
Fatalities Nighttime 7.42 (2.60) Fatalities per 100,000 people
during the night
Note. The data are weighted means based on the Fatality
Analysis Reporting System state-level panel for
1990–2010. Standard deviations are in parentheses.
Alcohol involvement is likely measured with error (Eisenberg
2003), and the
possibility exists that some states collected information on BAC
levels more
diligently than others.16 Focusing on nighttime and weekend
fatal crashes can
provide additional insight into the role of alcohol and help
address the mea-
surement error issue. As noted by Dee (1999), a substantial
proportion of fatal
crashes on weekends and at night involve alcohol.
As of 2011, 75 percent of the patients on the Arizona medical
marijuana
registry were male; 69 percent of the patients on the Colorado
registry were
male. There is also evidence that many medical marijuana
patients are below
the age of 40. Forty-eight percent of registered patients in
Montana and 42
percent of registered patients in Arizona were between the ages
of 18 and 40;
the average age of registered patients in Colorado was 40.17 To
the extent that
registered patients below the age of 40 are more likely to use
medical marijuana
recreationally, heterogeneous effects across the age distribution
might be
expected.
Figures 1–3 compare pre- and postlegalization traffic fatality
trends by age
16 We also experimented with calculating the alcohol-related
fatality rates with the imputed BAC
levels available in the FARS data. These estimates, which are
similar in terms of magnitude and
precision to those presented here, are available on request. See
Adams, Blackburn, and Cotti (2012)
for a discussion of the BAC imputation method.
17 For links to state registry data, see NORML, Medical
Marijuana (http://norml.org/index.cfm
?Group_IDp3391).
This content downloaded from 130.166.3.5 on Tue, 18 Nov 2014
03:00:05 AM
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
http://norml.org/index.cfm?Group_ID=3391
http://norml.org/index.cfm?Group_ID=3391
http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp
344 The Journal of LAW & ECONOMICS
Figure 1. Pre- and postlegalization trends in traffic fatality
rates, ages 15–19
Figure 2. Pre- and postlegalization trends in traffic fatality
rates, ages 20–39
group.18 In each figure, the solid line represents the average
traffic fatality rate
for the treated states (those that legalized medical marijuana).
The dashed line
represents the average fatality rate for the control states (those
that did not
legalize medical marijuana). Year 0 on the horizontal axis
represents the year in
which legalization took place. Control states were randomly
assigned a year of
legalization between 1996 and 2010.
18 Figures 1–3 are based on FARS data for the period 1990–
2010. Fatality rates are expressed relative
to year �1 and are weighted by the relevant population in state
s and year t.
This content downloaded from 130.166.3.5 on Tue, 18 Nov 2014
03:00:05 AM
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp
Medical Marijuana Laws 345
Figure 3. Pre- and postlegalization trends in traffic fatality
rates, ages 40 and older
Among teenagers (ages 15–19), young adults (ages 20–39), and
older adults
(ages 40 and above), average traffic fatality rates in the treated
states closely
follow those in the control states through year �1. This finding
is important
because it suggests that legalization was not preceded by, for
instance, new anti-
drunk-driving policies, increased spending on law enforcement,
or highway im-
provements. In the years immediately after legalization, average
traffic fatality
rates in MML states fall faster than average traffic fatality rates
in the control
states. This divergence is most pronounced among those 20–39.
Among teenagers
and older adults, average traffic fatality rates in the MML states
converge with
average traffic fatality rates in the control states 4–5 years after
legalization.
4.2. The Empirical Model
To further explore the relationship between legalization and
traffic fatalities,
we estimate the following baseline equation:
ln(Fatalities Total ) p b � b MML � X b � v � w � � , (2)st 0
1 st st 2 s t st
where s indexes states and t indexes years. The coefficient of
interest, b1, represents
the effect of legalizing medical marijuana.19 In alternative
specifications, we re-
place Fatalities Totalst with the remaining outcomes listed in
Table 4.
The vector Xst is composed of the controls described in Table
5, and vs and
wt are state and year fixed effects, respectively. Previous
studies provide evidence
that a variety of state-level policies can impact traffic fatalities.
For instance,
graduated driver-licensing regulations and stricter seat belt laws
are associated
19 This specification is based on Dee (2001), who examined the
relationship between .08 BAC laws
(making it illegal for drivers to have a BAC of .08 percent or
higher) and traffic fatalities.
This content downloaded from 130.166.3.5 on Tue, 18 Nov 2014
03:00:05 AM
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp
T
ab
le
5
In
d
ep
en
d
en
t
V
ar
ia
b
le
s
fo
r
th
e
F
at
al
it
y
A
n
al
ys
is
R
ep
o
rt
in
g
S
ys
te
m
A
n
al
ys
is
In
d
ep
en
d
en
t
V
ar
ia
b
le
M
ea
n
D
es
cr
ip
ti
o
n
M
M
L
a
.1
30
(.
3
34
)
E
q
u
al
s
o
n
e
if
a
st
at
e
h
ad
a
m
ed
ic
al
m
ar
ij
u
an
a
la
w
in
a
gi
ve
n
ye
ar
an
d
ze
ro
o
th
er
w
is
e
M
ea
n
A
ge
3
5
.9
0
(1
.6
6
)
M
ea
n
ag
e
o
f
th
e
st
at
e
p
o
p
u
la
ti
o
n
U
n
em
p
lo
ym
en
t
5
.8
7
(1
.8
7)
St
at
e
u
n
em
p
lo
ym
en
t
ra
te
In
co
m
e
1
0
.2
7
(.
15
6
)
N
at
u
ra
l
lo
ga
ri
th
m
o
f
st
at
e
re
al
in
co
m
e
p
er
ca
p
it
a
(2
00
0
$
)
M
il
es
D
ri
ve
n
1
4
.1
3
(2
.0
5
)
V
eh
ic
le
m
il
es
d
ri
ve
n
p
er
li
ce
n
se
d
d
ri
ve
r
(t
h
o
u
sa
n
d
s
o
f
m
il
es
)
D
ec
ri
m
in
al
iz
ed
a
.3
30
(.
4
70
)
E
q
u
al
s
o
n
e
if
a
st
at
e
h
ad
a
m
ar
ij
u
an
a
d
ec
ri
m
in
al
iz
at
io
n
la
w
in
a
gi
ve
n
ye
ar
an
d
ze
ro
o
th
er
w
is
e
D
ru
g
P
er
Se
.1
42
(.
3
45
)
E
q
u
al
s
o
n
e
if
a
st
at
e
h
ad
a
d
ru
g
p
er
se
la
w
in
a
gi
ve
n
ye
ar
an
d
ze
ro
o
th
er
w
is
e
G
D
L
a
.5
22
(.
4
93
)
E
q
u
al
s
o
n
e
if
a
st
at
e
h
ad
a
gr
ad
u
at
ed
d
ri
ve
r-
li
ce
n
si
n
g
la
w
w
it
h
an
in
te
rm
ed
ia
te
p
h
as
e
in
a
gi
ve
n
ye
ar
an
d
ze
ro
o
th
er
w
is
e
P
ri
m
ar
y
Se
at
B
el
ta
.4
61
(.
4
94
)
E
q
u
al
s
o
n
e
if
a
st
at
e
h
ad
a
p
ri
m
ar
y
se
at
b
el
t
la
w
in
a
gi
Is Marijuana a Gateway DrugAuthor(s) Jeffrey DeSimoneSou.docx
Is Marijuana a Gateway DrugAuthor(s) Jeffrey DeSimoneSou.docx
Is Marijuana a Gateway DrugAuthor(s) Jeffrey DeSimoneSou.docx
Is Marijuana a Gateway DrugAuthor(s) Jeffrey DeSimoneSou.docx
Is Marijuana a Gateway DrugAuthor(s) Jeffrey DeSimoneSou.docx
Is Marijuana a Gateway DrugAuthor(s) Jeffrey DeSimoneSou.docx
Is Marijuana a Gateway DrugAuthor(s) Jeffrey DeSimoneSou.docx
Is Marijuana a Gateway DrugAuthor(s) Jeffrey DeSimoneSou.docx
Is Marijuana a Gateway DrugAuthor(s) Jeffrey DeSimoneSou.docx
Is Marijuana a Gateway DrugAuthor(s) Jeffrey DeSimoneSou.docx
Is Marijuana a Gateway DrugAuthor(s) Jeffrey DeSimoneSou.docx
Is Marijuana a Gateway DrugAuthor(s) Jeffrey DeSimoneSou.docx
Is Marijuana a Gateway DrugAuthor(s) Jeffrey DeSimoneSou.docx
Is Marijuana a Gateway DrugAuthor(s) Jeffrey DeSimoneSou.docx
Is Marijuana a Gateway DrugAuthor(s) Jeffrey DeSimoneSou.docx
Is Marijuana a Gateway DrugAuthor(s) Jeffrey DeSimoneSou.docx
Is Marijuana a Gateway DrugAuthor(s) Jeffrey DeSimoneSou.docx
Is Marijuana a Gateway DrugAuthor(s) Jeffrey DeSimoneSou.docx
Is Marijuana a Gateway DrugAuthor(s) Jeffrey DeSimoneSou.docx
Is Marijuana a Gateway DrugAuthor(s) Jeffrey DeSimoneSou.docx
Is Marijuana a Gateway DrugAuthor(s) Jeffrey DeSimoneSou.docx
Is Marijuana a Gateway DrugAuthor(s) Jeffrey DeSimoneSou.docx
Is Marijuana a Gateway DrugAuthor(s) Jeffrey DeSimoneSou.docx
Is Marijuana a Gateway DrugAuthor(s) Jeffrey DeSimoneSou.docx
Is Marijuana a Gateway DrugAuthor(s) Jeffrey DeSimoneSou.docx
Is Marijuana a Gateway DrugAuthor(s) Jeffrey DeSimoneSou.docx
Is Marijuana a Gateway DrugAuthor(s) Jeffrey DeSimoneSou.docx
Is Marijuana a Gateway DrugAuthor(s) Jeffrey DeSimoneSou.docx
Is Marijuana a Gateway DrugAuthor(s) Jeffrey DeSimoneSou.docx
Is Marijuana a Gateway DrugAuthor(s) Jeffrey DeSimoneSou.docx
Is Marijuana a Gateway DrugAuthor(s) Jeffrey DeSimoneSou.docx
Is Marijuana a Gateway DrugAuthor(s) Jeffrey DeSimoneSou.docx
Is Marijuana a Gateway DrugAuthor(s) Jeffrey DeSimoneSou.docx
Is Marijuana a Gateway DrugAuthor(s) Jeffrey DeSimoneSou.docx
Is Marijuana a Gateway DrugAuthor(s) Jeffrey DeSimoneSou.docx
Is Marijuana a Gateway DrugAuthor(s) Jeffrey DeSimoneSou.docx
Is Marijuana a Gateway DrugAuthor(s) Jeffrey DeSimoneSou.docx
Is Marijuana a Gateway DrugAuthor(s) Jeffrey DeSimoneSou.docx
Is Marijuana a Gateway DrugAuthor(s) Jeffrey DeSimoneSou.docx
Is Marijuana a Gateway DrugAuthor(s) Jeffrey DeSimoneSou.docx
Is Marijuana a Gateway DrugAuthor(s) Jeffrey DeSimoneSou.docx
Is Marijuana a Gateway DrugAuthor(s) Jeffrey DeSimoneSou.docx
Is Marijuana a Gateway DrugAuthor(s) Jeffrey DeSimoneSou.docx
Is Marijuana a Gateway DrugAuthor(s) Jeffrey DeSimoneSou.docx
Is Marijuana a Gateway DrugAuthor(s) Jeffrey DeSimoneSou.docx
Is Marijuana a Gateway DrugAuthor(s) Jeffrey DeSimoneSou.docx
Is Marijuana a Gateway DrugAuthor(s) Jeffrey DeSimoneSou.docx
Is Marijuana a Gateway DrugAuthor(s) Jeffrey DeSimoneSou.docx
Is Marijuana a Gateway DrugAuthor(s) Jeffrey DeSimoneSou.docx
Is Marijuana a Gateway DrugAuthor(s) Jeffrey DeSimoneSou.docx
Is Marijuana a Gateway DrugAuthor(s) Jeffrey DeSimoneSou.docx
Is Marijuana a Gateway DrugAuthor(s) Jeffrey DeSimoneSou.docx
Is Marijuana a Gateway DrugAuthor(s) Jeffrey DeSimoneSou.docx
Is Marijuana a Gateway DrugAuthor(s) Jeffrey DeSimoneSou.docx
Is Marijuana a Gateway DrugAuthor(s) Jeffrey DeSimoneSou.docx
Is Marijuana a Gateway DrugAuthor(s) Jeffrey DeSimoneSou.docx
Is Marijuana a Gateway DrugAuthor(s) Jeffrey DeSimoneSou.docx
Is Marijuana a Gateway DrugAuthor(s) Jeffrey DeSimoneSou.docx
Is Marijuana a Gateway DrugAuthor(s) Jeffrey DeSimoneSou.docx
Is Marijuana a Gateway DrugAuthor(s) Jeffrey DeSimoneSou.docx
Is Marijuana a Gateway DrugAuthor(s) Jeffrey DeSimoneSou.docx
Is Marijuana a Gateway DrugAuthor(s) Jeffrey DeSimoneSou.docx
Is Marijuana a Gateway DrugAuthor(s) Jeffrey DeSimoneSou.docx
Is Marijuana a Gateway DrugAuthor(s) Jeffrey DeSimoneSou.docx
Is Marijuana a Gateway DrugAuthor(s) Jeffrey DeSimoneSou.docx
Is Marijuana a Gateway DrugAuthor(s) Jeffrey DeSimoneSou.docx
Is Marijuana a Gateway DrugAuthor(s) Jeffrey DeSimoneSou.docx
Is Marijuana a Gateway DrugAuthor(s) Jeffrey DeSimoneSou.docx
Is Marijuana a Gateway DrugAuthor(s) Jeffrey DeSimoneSou.docx
Is Marijuana a Gateway DrugAuthor(s) Jeffrey DeSimoneSou.docx
Is Marijuana a Gateway DrugAuthor(s) Jeffrey DeSimoneSou.docx
Is Marijuana a Gateway DrugAuthor(s) Jeffrey DeSimoneSou.docx
Is Marijuana a Gateway DrugAuthor(s) Jeffrey DeSimoneSou.docx
Is Marijuana a Gateway DrugAuthor(s) Jeffrey DeSimoneSou.docx
Is Marijuana a Gateway DrugAuthor(s) Jeffrey DeSimoneSou.docx
Is Marijuana a Gateway DrugAuthor(s) Jeffrey DeSimoneSou.docx
Is Marijuana a Gateway DrugAuthor(s) Jeffrey DeSimoneSou.docx
Is Marijuana a Gateway DrugAuthor(s) Jeffrey DeSimoneSou.docx
Is Marijuana a Gateway DrugAuthor(s) Jeffrey DeSimoneSou.docx
Is Marijuana a Gateway DrugAuthor(s) Jeffrey DeSimoneSou.docx
Is Marijuana a Gateway DrugAuthor(s) Jeffrey DeSimoneSou.docx
Is Marijuana a Gateway DrugAuthor(s) Jeffrey DeSimoneSou.docx
Is Marijuana a Gateway DrugAuthor(s) Jeffrey DeSimoneSou.docx
Is Marijuana a Gateway DrugAuthor(s) Jeffrey DeSimoneSou.docx
Is Marijuana a Gateway DrugAuthor(s) Jeffrey DeSimoneSou.docx
Is Marijuana a Gateway DrugAuthor(s) Jeffrey DeSimoneSou.docx
Is Marijuana a Gateway DrugAuthor(s) Jeffrey DeSimoneSou.docx
Is Marijuana a Gateway DrugAuthor(s) Jeffrey DeSimoneSou.docx
Is Marijuana a Gateway DrugAuthor(s) Jeffrey DeSimoneSou.docx
Is Marijuana a Gateway DrugAuthor(s) Jeffrey DeSimoneSou.docx
Is Marijuana a Gateway DrugAuthor(s) Jeffrey DeSimoneSou.docx
Is Marijuana a Gateway DrugAuthor(s) Jeffrey DeSimoneSou.docx
Is Marijuana a Gateway DrugAuthor(s) Jeffrey DeSimoneSou.docx
Is Marijuana a Gateway DrugAuthor(s) Jeffrey DeSimoneSou.docx
Is Marijuana a Gateway DrugAuthor(s) Jeffrey DeSimoneSou.docx
Is Marijuana a Gateway DrugAuthor(s) Jeffrey DeSimoneSou.docx
Is Marijuana a Gateway DrugAuthor(s) Jeffrey DeSimoneSou.docx
Is Marijuana a Gateway DrugAuthor(s) Jeffrey DeSimoneSou.docx
Is Marijuana a Gateway DrugAuthor(s) Jeffrey DeSimoneSou.docx
Is Marijuana a Gateway DrugAuthor(s) Jeffrey DeSimoneSou.docx
Is Marijuana a Gateway DrugAuthor(s) Jeffrey DeSimoneSou.docx
Is Marijuana a Gateway DrugAuthor(s) Jeffrey DeSimoneSou.docx
Is Marijuana a Gateway DrugAuthor(s) Jeffrey DeSimoneSou.docx
Is Marijuana a Gateway DrugAuthor(s) Jeffrey DeSimoneSou.docx
Is Marijuana a Gateway DrugAuthor(s) Jeffrey DeSimoneSou.docx
Is Marijuana a Gateway DrugAuthor(s) Jeffrey DeSimoneSou.docx
Is Marijuana a Gateway DrugAuthor(s) Jeffrey DeSimoneSou.docx
Is Marijuana a Gateway DrugAuthor(s) Jeffrey DeSimoneSou.docx
Is Marijuana a Gateway DrugAuthor(s) Jeffrey DeSimoneSou.docx
Is Marijuana a Gateway DrugAuthor(s) Jeffrey DeSimoneSou.docx
Is Marijuana a Gateway DrugAuthor(s) Jeffrey DeSimoneSou.docx
Is Marijuana a Gateway DrugAuthor(s) Jeffrey DeSimoneSou.docx
Is Marijuana a Gateway DrugAuthor(s) Jeffrey DeSimoneSou.docx
Is Marijuana a Gateway DrugAuthor(s) Jeffrey DeSimoneSou.docx
Is Marijuana a Gateway DrugAuthor(s) Jeffrey DeSimoneSou.docx
Is Marijuana a Gateway DrugAuthor(s) Jeffrey DeSimoneSou.docx
Is Marijuana a Gateway DrugAuthor(s) Jeffrey DeSimoneSou.docx
Is Marijuana a Gateway DrugAuthor(s) Jeffrey DeSimoneSou.docx
Is Marijuana a Gateway DrugAuthor(s) Jeffrey DeSimoneSou.docx
Is Marijuana a Gateway DrugAuthor(s) Jeffrey DeSimoneSou.docx
Is Marijuana a Gateway DrugAuthor(s) Jeffrey DeSimoneSou.docx
Is Marijuana a Gateway DrugAuthor(s) Jeffrey DeSimoneSou.docx
Is Marijuana a Gateway DrugAuthor(s) Jeffrey DeSimoneSou.docx
Is Marijuana a Gateway DrugAuthor(s) Jeffrey DeSimoneSou.docx
Is Marijuana a Gateway DrugAuthor(s) Jeffrey DeSimoneSou.docx
Is Marijuana a Gateway DrugAuthor(s) Jeffrey DeSimoneSou.docx
Is Marijuana a Gateway DrugAuthor(s) Jeffrey DeSimoneSou.docx
Is Marijuana a Gateway DrugAuthor(s) Jeffrey DeSimoneSou.docx
Is Marijuana a Gateway DrugAuthor(s) Jeffrey DeSimoneSou.docx
Is Marijuana a Gateway DrugAuthor(s) Jeffrey DeSimoneSou.docx
Is Marijuana a Gateway DrugAuthor(s) Jeffrey DeSimoneSou.docx
Is Marijuana a Gateway DrugAuthor(s) Jeffrey DeSimoneSou.docx
Is Marijuana a Gateway DrugAuthor(s) Jeffrey DeSimoneSou.docx
Is Marijuana a Gateway DrugAuthor(s) Jeffrey DeSimoneSou.docx
Is Marijuana a Gateway DrugAuthor(s) Jeffrey DeSimoneSou.docx
Is Marijuana a Gateway DrugAuthor(s) Jeffrey DeSimoneSou.docx
Is Marijuana a Gateway DrugAuthor(s) Jeffrey DeSimoneSou.docx
Is Marijuana a Gateway DrugAuthor(s) Jeffrey DeSimoneSou.docx
Is Marijuana a Gateway DrugAuthor(s) Jeffrey DeSimoneSou.docx
Is Marijuana a Gateway DrugAuthor(s) Jeffrey DeSimoneSou.docx
Is Marijuana a Gateway DrugAuthor(s) Jeffrey DeSimoneSou.docx
Is Marijuana a Gateway DrugAuthor(s) Jeffrey DeSimoneSou.docx
Is Marijuana a Gateway DrugAuthor(s) Jeffrey DeSimoneSou.docx
Is Marijuana a Gateway DrugAuthor(s) Jeffrey DeSimoneSou.docx
Is Marijuana a Gateway DrugAuthor(s) Jeffrey DeSimoneSou.docx
Is Marijuana a Gateway DrugAuthor(s) Jeffrey DeSimoneSou.docx
Is Marijuana a Gateway DrugAuthor(s) Jeffrey DeSimoneSou.docx
Is Marijuana a Gateway DrugAuthor(s) Jeffrey DeSimoneSou.docx
Is Marijuana a Gateway DrugAuthor(s) Jeffrey DeSimoneSou.docx
Is Marijuana a Gateway DrugAuthor(s) Jeffrey DeSimoneSou.docx
Is Marijuana a Gateway DrugAuthor(s) Jeffrey DeSimoneSou.docx
Is Marijuana a Gateway DrugAuthor(s) Jeffrey DeSimoneSou.docx
Is Marijuana a Gateway DrugAuthor(s) Jeffrey DeSimoneSou.docx
Is Marijuana a Gateway DrugAuthor(s) Jeffrey DeSimoneSou.docx
Is Marijuana a Gateway DrugAuthor(s) Jeffrey DeSimoneSou.docx
Is Marijuana a Gateway DrugAuthor(s) Jeffrey DeSimoneSou.docx
Is Marijuana a Gateway DrugAuthor(s) Jeffrey DeSimoneSou.docx
Is Marijuana a Gateway DrugAuthor(s) Jeffrey DeSimoneSou.docx
Is Marijuana a Gateway DrugAuthor(s) Jeffrey DeSimoneSou.docx
Is Marijuana a Gateway DrugAuthor(s) Jeffrey DeSimoneSou.docx
Is Marijuana a Gateway DrugAuthor(s) Jeffrey DeSimoneSou.docx
Is Marijuana a Gateway DrugAuthor(s) Jeffrey DeSimoneSou.docx
Is Marijuana a Gateway DrugAuthor(s) Jeffrey DeSimoneSou.docx
Is Marijuana a Gateway DrugAuthor(s) Jeffrey DeSimoneSou.docx
Is Marijuana a Gateway DrugAuthor(s) Jeffrey DeSimoneSou.docx
Is Marijuana a Gateway DrugAuthor(s) Jeffrey DeSimoneSou.docx
Is Marijuana a Gateway DrugAuthor(s) Jeffrey DeSimoneSou.docx
Is Marijuana a Gateway DrugAuthor(s) Jeffrey DeSimoneSou.docx
Is Marijuana a Gateway DrugAuthor(s) Jeffrey DeSimoneSou.docx
Is Marijuana a Gateway DrugAuthor(s) Jeffrey DeSimoneSou.docx
Is Marijuana a Gateway DrugAuthor(s) Jeffrey DeSimoneSou.docx
Is Marijuana a Gateway DrugAuthor(s) Jeffrey DeSimoneSou.docx
Is Marijuana a Gateway DrugAuthor(s) Jeffrey DeSimoneSou.docx
Is Marijuana a Gateway DrugAuthor(s) Jeffrey DeSimoneSou.docx
Is Marijuana a Gateway DrugAuthor(s) Jeffrey DeSimoneSou.docx
Is Marijuana a Gateway DrugAuthor(s) Jeffrey DeSimoneSou.docx
Is Marijuana a Gateway DrugAuthor(s) Jeffrey DeSimoneSou.docx
Is Marijuana a Gateway DrugAuthor(s) Jeffrey DeSimoneSou.docx
Is Marijuana a Gateway DrugAuthor(s) Jeffrey DeSimoneSou.docx
Is Marijuana a Gateway DrugAuthor(s) Jeffrey DeSimoneSou.docx
Is Marijuana a Gateway DrugAuthor(s) Jeffrey DeSimoneSou.docx
Is Marijuana a Gateway DrugAuthor(s) Jeffrey DeSimoneSou.docx
Is Marijuana a Gateway DrugAuthor(s) Jeffrey DeSimoneSou.docx
Is Marijuana a Gateway DrugAuthor(s) Jeffrey DeSimoneSou.docx
Is Marijuana a Gateway DrugAuthor(s) Jeffrey DeSimoneSou.docx
Is Marijuana a Gateway DrugAuthor(s) Jeffrey DeSimoneSou.docx
Is Marijuana a Gateway DrugAuthor(s) Jeffrey DeSimoneSou.docx
Is Marijuana a Gateway DrugAuthor(s) Jeffrey DeSimoneSou.docx
Is Marijuana a Gateway DrugAuthor(s) Jeffrey DeSimoneSou.docx
Is Marijuana a Gateway DrugAuthor(s) Jeffrey DeSimoneSou.docx
Is Marijuana a Gateway DrugAuthor(s) Jeffrey DeSimoneSou.docx
Is Marijuana a Gateway DrugAuthor(s) Jeffrey DeSimoneSou.docx
Is Marijuana a Gateway DrugAuthor(s) Jeffrey DeSimoneSou.docx
Is Marijuana a Gateway DrugAuthor(s) Jeffrey DeSimoneSou.docx
Is Marijuana a Gateway DrugAuthor(s) Jeffrey DeSimoneSou.docx
Is Marijuana a Gateway DrugAuthor(s) Jeffrey DeSimoneSou.docx
Is Marijuana a Gateway DrugAuthor(s) Jeffrey DeSimoneSou.docx
Is Marijuana a Gateway DrugAuthor(s) Jeffrey DeSimoneSou.docx
Is Marijuana a Gateway DrugAuthor(s) Jeffrey DeSimoneSou.docx
Is Marijuana a Gateway DrugAuthor(s) Jeffrey DeSimoneSou.docx
Is Marijuana a Gateway DrugAuthor(s) Jeffrey DeSimoneSou.docx
Is Marijuana a Gateway DrugAuthor(s) Jeffrey DeSimoneSou.docx
Is Marijuana a Gateway DrugAuthor(s) Jeffrey DeSimoneSou.docx
Is Marijuana a Gateway DrugAuthor(s) Jeffrey DeSimoneSou.docx
Is Marijuana a Gateway DrugAuthor(s) Jeffrey DeSimoneSou.docx
Is Marijuana a Gateway DrugAuthor(s) Jeffrey DeSimoneSou.docx
Is Marijuana a Gateway DrugAuthor(s) Jeffrey DeSimoneSou.docx
Is Marijuana a Gateway DrugAuthor(s) Jeffrey DeSimoneSou.docx
Is Marijuana a Gateway DrugAuthor(s) Jeffrey DeSimoneSou.docx
Is Marijuana a Gateway DrugAuthor(s) Jeffrey DeSimoneSou.docx
Is Marijuana a Gateway DrugAuthor(s) Jeffrey DeSimoneSou.docx
Is Marijuana a Gateway DrugAuthor(s) Jeffrey DeSimoneSou.docx
Is Marijuana a Gateway DrugAuthor(s) Jeffrey DeSimoneSou.docx
Is Marijuana a Gateway DrugAuthor(s) Jeffrey DeSimoneSou.docx
Is Marijuana a Gateway DrugAuthor(s) Jeffrey DeSimoneSou.docx
Is Marijuana a Gateway DrugAuthor(s) Jeffrey DeSimoneSou.docx
Is Marijuana a Gateway DrugAuthor(s) Jeffrey DeSimoneSou.docx
Is Marijuana a Gateway DrugAuthor(s) Jeffrey DeSimoneSou.docx
Is Marijuana a Gateway DrugAuthor(s) Jeffrey DeSimoneSou.docx
Is Marijuana a Gateway DrugAuthor(s) Jeffrey DeSimoneSou.docx
Is Marijuana a Gateway DrugAuthor(s) Jeffrey DeSimoneSou.docx
Is Marijuana a Gateway DrugAuthor(s) Jeffrey DeSimoneSou.docx
Is Marijuana a Gateway DrugAuthor(s) Jeffrey DeSimoneSou.docx
Is Marijuana a Gateway DrugAuthor(s) Jeffrey DeSimoneSou.docx
Is Marijuana a Gateway DrugAuthor(s) Jeffrey DeSimoneSou.docx
Is Marijuana a Gateway DrugAuthor(s) Jeffrey DeSimoneSou.docx
Is Marijuana a Gateway DrugAuthor(s) Jeffrey DeSimoneSou.docx
Is Marijuana a Gateway DrugAuthor(s) Jeffrey DeSimoneSou.docx
Is Marijuana a Gateway DrugAuthor(s) Jeffrey DeSimoneSou.docx
Is Marijuana a Gateway DrugAuthor(s) Jeffrey DeSimoneSou.docx
Is Marijuana a Gateway DrugAuthor(s) Jeffrey DeSimoneSou.docx
Is Marijuana a Gateway DrugAuthor(s) Jeffrey DeSimoneSou.docx
Is Marijuana a Gateway DrugAuthor(s) Jeffrey DeSimoneSou.docx
Is Marijuana a Gateway DrugAuthor(s) Jeffrey DeSimoneSou.docx

More Related Content

Similar to Is Marijuana a Gateway DrugAuthor(s) Jeffrey DeSimoneSou.docx

Predicting active compounds for lung cancer based on quantitative structure-a...
Predicting active compounds for lung cancer based on quantitative structure-a...Predicting active compounds for lung cancer based on quantitative structure-a...
Predicting active compounds for lung cancer based on quantitative structure-a...IJECEIAES
 
An Actionable Annotation Scoring Framework For Gas Chromatography - High Reso...
An Actionable Annotation Scoring Framework For Gas Chromatography - High Reso...An Actionable Annotation Scoring Framework For Gas Chromatography - High Reso...
An Actionable Annotation Scoring Framework For Gas Chromatography - High Reso...Nicole Heredia
 
A Next-Generation Risk Assessment Case Study For Coumarin In Cosmetic Products
A Next-Generation Risk Assessment Case Study For Coumarin In Cosmetic ProductsA Next-Generation Risk Assessment Case Study For Coumarin In Cosmetic Products
A Next-Generation Risk Assessment Case Study For Coumarin In Cosmetic ProductsMonique Carr
 
Caroline Hurley MATH499 Project
Caroline Hurley MATH499 ProjectCaroline Hurley MATH499 Project
Caroline Hurley MATH499 ProjectCaroline Hurley
 
computational chemistry
computational chemistrycomputational chemistry
computational chemistrySAMUELAKANDE3
 
EPA Guidelines for Carcinogen Risk Assessment.pptx
EPA Guidelines for Carcinogen Risk Assessment.pptxEPA Guidelines for Carcinogen Risk Assessment.pptx
EPA Guidelines for Carcinogen Risk Assessment.pptxMegh Vithalkar
 
Computational (In Silico) Pharmacology.pdf
Computational (In Silico) Pharmacology.pdfComputational (In Silico) Pharmacology.pdf
Computational (In Silico) Pharmacology.pdfssuser515ca21
 
Analysis of pk data- Pop PK analysis
Analysis of pk data- Pop PK analysisAnalysis of pk data- Pop PK analysis
Analysis of pk data- Pop PK analysisGayathri Ravi
 
Simulating brain reaction to
Simulating brain reaction toSimulating brain reaction to
Simulating brain reaction toijaia
 
The Stigma Faced by Lung Cancer Patients: A Link Between Information Anchorin...
The Stigma Faced by Lung Cancer Patients: A Link Between Information Anchorin...The Stigma Faced by Lung Cancer Patients: A Link Between Information Anchorin...
The Stigma Faced by Lung Cancer Patients: A Link Between Information Anchorin...KaylahPolzin
 
Applications of mass spectrometry.seminar.pptx
Applications of mass spectrometry.seminar.pptxApplications of mass spectrometry.seminar.pptx
Applications of mass spectrometry.seminar.pptxAsif Shaikh
 
Modern p'ceutics drug excipient interaction
Modern p'ceutics drug excipient interactionModern p'ceutics drug excipient interaction
Modern p'ceutics drug excipient interactionArjunDhawale
 
Megan St. JacquesAug 5, 2021 125 PMMegan St. JacquesLiberty
Megan St. JacquesAug 5, 2021 125 PMMegan St. JacquesLibertyMegan St. JacquesAug 5, 2021 125 PMMegan St. JacquesLiberty
Megan St. JacquesAug 5, 2021 125 PMMegan St. JacquesLibertyAbramMartino96
 
Luisetto m, mashori gr, luca c. new pharmacological strategies in some metabo...
Luisetto m, mashori gr, luca c. new pharmacological strategies in some metabo...Luisetto m, mashori gr, luca c. new pharmacological strategies in some metabo...
Luisetto m, mashori gr, luca c. new pharmacological strategies in some metabo...M. Luisetto Pharm.D.Spec. Pharmacology
 
Novel Hybrid Molecules of Quinazoline Chalcone Derivatives: Synthesis and Stu...
Novel Hybrid Molecules of Quinazoline Chalcone Derivatives: Synthesis and Stu...Novel Hybrid Molecules of Quinazoline Chalcone Derivatives: Synthesis and Stu...
Novel Hybrid Molecules of Quinazoline Chalcone Derivatives: Synthesis and Stu...Ratnakaram Venkata Nadh
 
Calais, gerald j fuzzy cognitive maps theroy
Calais, gerald j fuzzy cognitive maps theroyCalais, gerald j fuzzy cognitive maps theroy
Calais, gerald j fuzzy cognitive maps theroyWilliam Kritsonis
 
Calais, gerald j fuzzy cognitive maps theroy
Calais, gerald j fuzzy cognitive maps theroyCalais, gerald j fuzzy cognitive maps theroy
Calais, gerald j fuzzy cognitive maps theroyWilliam Kritsonis
 

Similar to Is Marijuana a Gateway DrugAuthor(s) Jeffrey DeSimoneSou.docx (20)

Predicting active compounds for lung cancer based on quantitative structure-a...
Predicting active compounds for lung cancer based on quantitative structure-a...Predicting active compounds for lung cancer based on quantitative structure-a...
Predicting active compounds for lung cancer based on quantitative structure-a...
 
An Actionable Annotation Scoring Framework For Gas Chromatography - High Reso...
An Actionable Annotation Scoring Framework For Gas Chromatography - High Reso...An Actionable Annotation Scoring Framework For Gas Chromatography - High Reso...
An Actionable Annotation Scoring Framework For Gas Chromatography - High Reso...
 
A Next-Generation Risk Assessment Case Study For Coumarin In Cosmetic Products
A Next-Generation Risk Assessment Case Study For Coumarin In Cosmetic ProductsA Next-Generation Risk Assessment Case Study For Coumarin In Cosmetic Products
A Next-Generation Risk Assessment Case Study For Coumarin In Cosmetic Products
 
Caroline Hurley MATH499 Project
Caroline Hurley MATH499 ProjectCaroline Hurley MATH499 Project
Caroline Hurley MATH499 Project
 
Cra helwan
Cra helwanCra helwan
Cra helwan
 
Drug design and toxicology
Drug design and toxicologyDrug design and toxicology
Drug design and toxicology
 
computational chemistry
computational chemistrycomputational chemistry
computational chemistry
 
EPA Guidelines for Carcinogen Risk Assessment.pptx
EPA Guidelines for Carcinogen Risk Assessment.pptxEPA Guidelines for Carcinogen Risk Assessment.pptx
EPA Guidelines for Carcinogen Risk Assessment.pptx
 
Computational (In Silico) Pharmacology.pdf
Computational (In Silico) Pharmacology.pdfComputational (In Silico) Pharmacology.pdf
Computational (In Silico) Pharmacology.pdf
 
Analysis of pk data- Pop PK analysis
Analysis of pk data- Pop PK analysisAnalysis of pk data- Pop PK analysis
Analysis of pk data- Pop PK analysis
 
Drug Design
Drug DesignDrug Design
Drug Design
 
Simulating brain reaction to
Simulating brain reaction toSimulating brain reaction to
Simulating brain reaction to
 
The Stigma Faced by Lung Cancer Patients: A Link Between Information Anchorin...
The Stigma Faced by Lung Cancer Patients: A Link Between Information Anchorin...The Stigma Faced by Lung Cancer Patients: A Link Between Information Anchorin...
The Stigma Faced by Lung Cancer Patients: A Link Between Information Anchorin...
 
Applications of mass spectrometry.seminar.pptx
Applications of mass spectrometry.seminar.pptxApplications of mass spectrometry.seminar.pptx
Applications of mass spectrometry.seminar.pptx
 
Modern p'ceutics drug excipient interaction
Modern p'ceutics drug excipient interactionModern p'ceutics drug excipient interaction
Modern p'ceutics drug excipient interaction
 
Megan St. JacquesAug 5, 2021 125 PMMegan St. JacquesLiberty
Megan St. JacquesAug 5, 2021 125 PMMegan St. JacquesLibertyMegan St. JacquesAug 5, 2021 125 PMMegan St. JacquesLiberty
Megan St. JacquesAug 5, 2021 125 PMMegan St. JacquesLiberty
 
Luisetto m, mashori gr, luca c. new pharmacological strategies in some metabo...
Luisetto m, mashori gr, luca c. new pharmacological strategies in some metabo...Luisetto m, mashori gr, luca c. new pharmacological strategies in some metabo...
Luisetto m, mashori gr, luca c. new pharmacological strategies in some metabo...
 
Novel Hybrid Molecules of Quinazoline Chalcone Derivatives: Synthesis and Stu...
Novel Hybrid Molecules of Quinazoline Chalcone Derivatives: Synthesis and Stu...Novel Hybrid Molecules of Quinazoline Chalcone Derivatives: Synthesis and Stu...
Novel Hybrid Molecules of Quinazoline Chalcone Derivatives: Synthesis and Stu...
 
Calais, gerald j fuzzy cognitive maps theroy
Calais, gerald j fuzzy cognitive maps theroyCalais, gerald j fuzzy cognitive maps theroy
Calais, gerald j fuzzy cognitive maps theroy
 
Calais, gerald j fuzzy cognitive maps theroy
Calais, gerald j fuzzy cognitive maps theroyCalais, gerald j fuzzy cognitive maps theroy
Calais, gerald j fuzzy cognitive maps theroy
 

More from priestmanmable

9©iStockphotoThinkstockPlanning for Material and Reso.docx
9©iStockphotoThinkstockPlanning for Material and Reso.docx9©iStockphotoThinkstockPlanning for Material and Reso.docx
9©iStockphotoThinkstockPlanning for Material and Reso.docxpriestmanmable
 
a 12 page paper on how individuals of color would be a more dominant.docx
a 12 page paper on how individuals of color would be a more dominant.docxa 12 page paper on how individuals of color would be a more dominant.docx
a 12 page paper on how individuals of color would be a more dominant.docxpriestmanmable
 
978-1-5386-6589-318$31.00 ©2018 IEEE COSO Framework for .docx
978-1-5386-6589-318$31.00 ©2018 IEEE COSO Framework for .docx978-1-5386-6589-318$31.00 ©2018 IEEE COSO Framework for .docx
978-1-5386-6589-318$31.00 ©2018 IEEE COSO Framework for .docxpriestmanmable
 
92 Academic Journal Article Critique  Help with Journal Ar.docx
92 Academic Journal Article Critique  Help with Journal Ar.docx92 Academic Journal Article Critique  Help with Journal Ar.docx
92 Academic Journal Article Critique  Help with Journal Ar.docxpriestmanmable
 
A ) Society perspective90 year old female, Mrs. Ruth, from h.docx
A ) Society perspective90 year old female, Mrs. Ruth, from h.docxA ) Society perspective90 year old female, Mrs. Ruth, from h.docx
A ) Society perspective90 year old female, Mrs. Ruth, from h.docxpriestmanmable
 
9 dissuasion question Bartol, C. R., & Bartol, A. M. (2017)..docx
9 dissuasion question Bartol, C. R., & Bartol, A. M. (2017)..docx9 dissuasion question Bartol, C. R., & Bartol, A. M. (2017)..docx
9 dissuasion question Bartol, C. R., & Bartol, A. M. (2017)..docxpriestmanmable
 
9 AssignmentAssignment Typologies of Sexual AssaultsT.docx
9 AssignmentAssignment Typologies of Sexual AssaultsT.docx9 AssignmentAssignment Typologies of Sexual AssaultsT.docx
9 AssignmentAssignment Typologies of Sexual AssaultsT.docxpriestmanmable
 
9 0 0 0 09 7 8 0 1 3 4 4 7 7 4 0 4ISBN-13 978-0-13-44.docx
9 0 0 0 09 7 8 0 1 3 4 4 7 7 4 0 4ISBN-13 978-0-13-44.docx9 0 0 0 09 7 8 0 1 3 4 4 7 7 4 0 4ISBN-13 978-0-13-44.docx
9 0 0 0 09 7 8 0 1 3 4 4 7 7 4 0 4ISBN-13 978-0-13-44.docxpriestmanmable
 
900 BritishJournalofNursing,2013,Vol22,No15©2.docx
900 BritishJournalofNursing,2013,Vol22,No15©2.docx900 BritishJournalofNursing,2013,Vol22,No15©2.docx
900 BritishJournalofNursing,2013,Vol22,No15©2.docxpriestmanmable
 
9 Augustine Confessions (selections) Augustine of Hi.docx
9 Augustine Confessions (selections) Augustine of Hi.docx9 Augustine Confessions (selections) Augustine of Hi.docx
9 Augustine Confessions (selections) Augustine of Hi.docxpriestmanmable
 
8.3 Intercultural CommunicationLearning Objectives1. Define in.docx
8.3 Intercultural CommunicationLearning Objectives1. Define in.docx8.3 Intercultural CommunicationLearning Objectives1. Define in.docx
8.3 Intercultural CommunicationLearning Objectives1. Define in.docxpriestmanmable
 
8413 906 AMLife in a Toxic Country - NYTimes.comPage 1 .docx
8413 906 AMLife in a Toxic Country - NYTimes.comPage 1 .docx8413 906 AMLife in a Toxic Country - NYTimes.comPage 1 .docx
8413 906 AMLife in a Toxic Country - NYTimes.comPage 1 .docxpriestmanmable
 
8. A 2 x 2 Experimental Design - Quality and Economy (x1 and x2.docx
8. A 2 x 2 Experimental Design - Quality and Economy (x1 and x2.docx8. A 2 x 2 Experimental Design - Quality and Economy (x1 and x2.docx
8. A 2 x 2 Experimental Design - Quality and Economy (x1 and x2.docxpriestmanmable
 
800 Words 42-year-old man presents to ED with 2-day history .docx
800 Words 42-year-old man presents to ED with 2-day history .docx800 Words 42-year-old man presents to ED with 2-day history .docx
800 Words 42-year-old man presents to ED with 2-day history .docxpriestmanmable
 
8.1 What Is Corporate StrategyLO 8-1Define corporate strategy.docx
8.1 What Is Corporate StrategyLO 8-1Define corporate strategy.docx8.1 What Is Corporate StrategyLO 8-1Define corporate strategy.docx
8.1 What Is Corporate StrategyLO 8-1Define corporate strategy.docxpriestmanmable
 
8.0 RESEARCH METHODS These guidelines address postgr.docx
8.0  RESEARCH METHODS  These guidelines address postgr.docx8.0  RESEARCH METHODS  These guidelines address postgr.docx
8.0 RESEARCH METHODS These guidelines address postgr.docxpriestmanmable
 
95People of AppalachianHeritageChapter 5KATHLEEN.docx
95People of AppalachianHeritageChapter 5KATHLEEN.docx95People of AppalachianHeritageChapter 5KATHLEEN.docx
95People of AppalachianHeritageChapter 5KATHLEEN.docxpriestmanmable
 
9 781292 041452ISBN 978-1-29204-145-2Forensic Science.docx
9 781292 041452ISBN 978-1-29204-145-2Forensic Science.docx9 781292 041452ISBN 978-1-29204-145-2Forensic Science.docx
9 781292 041452ISBN 978-1-29204-145-2Forensic Science.docxpriestmanmable
 
8-10 slide Powerpoint The example company is Tesla.Instructions.docx
8-10 slide Powerpoint The example company is Tesla.Instructions.docx8-10 slide Powerpoint The example company is Tesla.Instructions.docx
8-10 slide Powerpoint The example company is Tesla.Instructions.docxpriestmanmable
 
8Network Security April 2020FEATUREAre your IT staf.docx
8Network Security  April 2020FEATUREAre your IT staf.docx8Network Security  April 2020FEATUREAre your IT staf.docx
8Network Security April 2020FEATUREAre your IT staf.docxpriestmanmable
 

More from priestmanmable (20)

9©iStockphotoThinkstockPlanning for Material and Reso.docx
9©iStockphotoThinkstockPlanning for Material and Reso.docx9©iStockphotoThinkstockPlanning for Material and Reso.docx
9©iStockphotoThinkstockPlanning for Material and Reso.docx
 
a 12 page paper on how individuals of color would be a more dominant.docx
a 12 page paper on how individuals of color would be a more dominant.docxa 12 page paper on how individuals of color would be a more dominant.docx
a 12 page paper on how individuals of color would be a more dominant.docx
 
978-1-5386-6589-318$31.00 ©2018 IEEE COSO Framework for .docx
978-1-5386-6589-318$31.00 ©2018 IEEE COSO Framework for .docx978-1-5386-6589-318$31.00 ©2018 IEEE COSO Framework for .docx
978-1-5386-6589-318$31.00 ©2018 IEEE COSO Framework for .docx
 
92 Academic Journal Article Critique  Help with Journal Ar.docx
92 Academic Journal Article Critique  Help with Journal Ar.docx92 Academic Journal Article Critique  Help with Journal Ar.docx
92 Academic Journal Article Critique  Help with Journal Ar.docx
 
A ) Society perspective90 year old female, Mrs. Ruth, from h.docx
A ) Society perspective90 year old female, Mrs. Ruth, from h.docxA ) Society perspective90 year old female, Mrs. Ruth, from h.docx
A ) Society perspective90 year old female, Mrs. Ruth, from h.docx
 
9 dissuasion question Bartol, C. R., & Bartol, A. M. (2017)..docx
9 dissuasion question Bartol, C. R., & Bartol, A. M. (2017)..docx9 dissuasion question Bartol, C. R., & Bartol, A. M. (2017)..docx
9 dissuasion question Bartol, C. R., & Bartol, A. M. (2017)..docx
 
9 AssignmentAssignment Typologies of Sexual AssaultsT.docx
9 AssignmentAssignment Typologies of Sexual AssaultsT.docx9 AssignmentAssignment Typologies of Sexual AssaultsT.docx
9 AssignmentAssignment Typologies of Sexual AssaultsT.docx
 
9 0 0 0 09 7 8 0 1 3 4 4 7 7 4 0 4ISBN-13 978-0-13-44.docx
9 0 0 0 09 7 8 0 1 3 4 4 7 7 4 0 4ISBN-13 978-0-13-44.docx9 0 0 0 09 7 8 0 1 3 4 4 7 7 4 0 4ISBN-13 978-0-13-44.docx
9 0 0 0 09 7 8 0 1 3 4 4 7 7 4 0 4ISBN-13 978-0-13-44.docx
 
900 BritishJournalofNursing,2013,Vol22,No15©2.docx
900 BritishJournalofNursing,2013,Vol22,No15©2.docx900 BritishJournalofNursing,2013,Vol22,No15©2.docx
900 BritishJournalofNursing,2013,Vol22,No15©2.docx
 
9 Augustine Confessions (selections) Augustine of Hi.docx
9 Augustine Confessions (selections) Augustine of Hi.docx9 Augustine Confessions (selections) Augustine of Hi.docx
9 Augustine Confessions (selections) Augustine of Hi.docx
 
8.3 Intercultural CommunicationLearning Objectives1. Define in.docx
8.3 Intercultural CommunicationLearning Objectives1. Define in.docx8.3 Intercultural CommunicationLearning Objectives1. Define in.docx
8.3 Intercultural CommunicationLearning Objectives1. Define in.docx
 
8413 906 AMLife in a Toxic Country - NYTimes.comPage 1 .docx
8413 906 AMLife in a Toxic Country - NYTimes.comPage 1 .docx8413 906 AMLife in a Toxic Country - NYTimes.comPage 1 .docx
8413 906 AMLife in a Toxic Country - NYTimes.comPage 1 .docx
 
8. A 2 x 2 Experimental Design - Quality and Economy (x1 and x2.docx
8. A 2 x 2 Experimental Design - Quality and Economy (x1 and x2.docx8. A 2 x 2 Experimental Design - Quality and Economy (x1 and x2.docx
8. A 2 x 2 Experimental Design - Quality and Economy (x1 and x2.docx
 
800 Words 42-year-old man presents to ED with 2-day history .docx
800 Words 42-year-old man presents to ED with 2-day history .docx800 Words 42-year-old man presents to ED with 2-day history .docx
800 Words 42-year-old man presents to ED with 2-day history .docx
 
8.1 What Is Corporate StrategyLO 8-1Define corporate strategy.docx
8.1 What Is Corporate StrategyLO 8-1Define corporate strategy.docx8.1 What Is Corporate StrategyLO 8-1Define corporate strategy.docx
8.1 What Is Corporate StrategyLO 8-1Define corporate strategy.docx
 
8.0 RESEARCH METHODS These guidelines address postgr.docx
8.0  RESEARCH METHODS  These guidelines address postgr.docx8.0  RESEARCH METHODS  These guidelines address postgr.docx
8.0 RESEARCH METHODS These guidelines address postgr.docx
 
95People of AppalachianHeritageChapter 5KATHLEEN.docx
95People of AppalachianHeritageChapter 5KATHLEEN.docx95People of AppalachianHeritageChapter 5KATHLEEN.docx
95People of AppalachianHeritageChapter 5KATHLEEN.docx
 
9 781292 041452ISBN 978-1-29204-145-2Forensic Science.docx
9 781292 041452ISBN 978-1-29204-145-2Forensic Science.docx9 781292 041452ISBN 978-1-29204-145-2Forensic Science.docx
9 781292 041452ISBN 978-1-29204-145-2Forensic Science.docx
 
8-10 slide Powerpoint The example company is Tesla.Instructions.docx
8-10 slide Powerpoint The example company is Tesla.Instructions.docx8-10 slide Powerpoint The example company is Tesla.Instructions.docx
8-10 slide Powerpoint The example company is Tesla.Instructions.docx
 
8Network Security April 2020FEATUREAre your IT staf.docx
8Network Security  April 2020FEATUREAre your IT staf.docx8Network Security  April 2020FEATUREAre your IT staf.docx
8Network Security April 2020FEATUREAre your IT staf.docx
 

Recently uploaded

Unit-IV- Pharma. Marketing Channels.pptx
Unit-IV- Pharma. Marketing Channels.pptxUnit-IV- Pharma. Marketing Channels.pptx
Unit-IV- Pharma. Marketing Channels.pptxVishalSingh1417
 
Grant Readiness 101 TechSoup and Remy Consulting
Grant Readiness 101 TechSoup and Remy ConsultingGrant Readiness 101 TechSoup and Remy Consulting
Grant Readiness 101 TechSoup and Remy ConsultingTechSoup
 
1029 - Danh muc Sach Giao Khoa 10 . pdf
1029 -  Danh muc Sach Giao Khoa 10 . pdf1029 -  Danh muc Sach Giao Khoa 10 . pdf
1029 - Danh muc Sach Giao Khoa 10 . pdfQucHHunhnh
 
Micro-Scholarship, What it is, How can it help me.pdf
Micro-Scholarship, What it is, How can it help me.pdfMicro-Scholarship, What it is, How can it help me.pdf
Micro-Scholarship, What it is, How can it help me.pdfPoh-Sun Goh
 
Kodo Millet PPT made by Ghanshyam bairwa college of Agriculture kumher bhara...
Kodo Millet  PPT made by Ghanshyam bairwa college of Agriculture kumher bhara...Kodo Millet  PPT made by Ghanshyam bairwa college of Agriculture kumher bhara...
Kodo Millet PPT made by Ghanshyam bairwa college of Agriculture kumher bhara...pradhanghanshyam7136
 
Explore beautiful and ugly buildings. Mathematics helps us create beautiful d...
Explore beautiful and ugly buildings. Mathematics helps us create beautiful d...Explore beautiful and ugly buildings. Mathematics helps us create beautiful d...
Explore beautiful and ugly buildings. Mathematics helps us create beautiful d...christianmathematics
 
Seal of Good Local Governance (SGLG) 2024Final.pptx
Seal of Good Local Governance (SGLG) 2024Final.pptxSeal of Good Local Governance (SGLG) 2024Final.pptx
Seal of Good Local Governance (SGLG) 2024Final.pptxnegromaestrong
 
Key note speaker Neum_Admir Softic_ENG.pdf
Key note speaker Neum_Admir Softic_ENG.pdfKey note speaker Neum_Admir Softic_ENG.pdf
Key note speaker Neum_Admir Softic_ENG.pdfAdmir Softic
 
Jual Obat Aborsi Hongkong ( Asli No.1 ) 085657271886 Obat Penggugur Kandungan...
Jual Obat Aborsi Hongkong ( Asli No.1 ) 085657271886 Obat Penggugur Kandungan...Jual Obat Aborsi Hongkong ( Asli No.1 ) 085657271886 Obat Penggugur Kandungan...
Jual Obat Aborsi Hongkong ( Asli No.1 ) 085657271886 Obat Penggugur Kandungan...ZurliaSoop
 
Russian Escort Service in Delhi 11k Hotel Foreigner Russian Call Girls in Delhi
Russian Escort Service in Delhi 11k Hotel Foreigner Russian Call Girls in DelhiRussian Escort Service in Delhi 11k Hotel Foreigner Russian Call Girls in Delhi
Russian Escort Service in Delhi 11k Hotel Foreigner Russian Call Girls in Delhikauryashika82
 
How to Create and Manage Wizard in Odoo 17
How to Create and Manage Wizard in Odoo 17How to Create and Manage Wizard in Odoo 17
How to Create and Manage Wizard in Odoo 17Celine George
 
Food safety_Challenges food safety laboratories_.pdf
Food safety_Challenges food safety laboratories_.pdfFood safety_Challenges food safety laboratories_.pdf
Food safety_Challenges food safety laboratories_.pdfSherif Taha
 
Unit-IV; Professional Sales Representative (PSR).pptx
Unit-IV; Professional Sales Representative (PSR).pptxUnit-IV; Professional Sales Representative (PSR).pptx
Unit-IV; Professional Sales Representative (PSR).pptxVishalSingh1417
 
Holdier Curriculum Vitae (April 2024).pdf
Holdier Curriculum Vitae (April 2024).pdfHoldier Curriculum Vitae (April 2024).pdf
Holdier Curriculum Vitae (April 2024).pdfagholdier
 
Application orientated numerical on hev.ppt
Application orientated numerical on hev.pptApplication orientated numerical on hev.ppt
Application orientated numerical on hev.pptRamjanShidvankar
 
SKILL OF INTRODUCING THE LESSON MICRO SKILLS.pptx
SKILL OF INTRODUCING THE LESSON MICRO SKILLS.pptxSKILL OF INTRODUCING THE LESSON MICRO SKILLS.pptx
SKILL OF INTRODUCING THE LESSON MICRO SKILLS.pptxAmanpreet Kaur
 
psychiatric nursing HISTORY COLLECTION .docx
psychiatric  nursing HISTORY  COLLECTION  .docxpsychiatric  nursing HISTORY  COLLECTION  .docx
psychiatric nursing HISTORY COLLECTION .docxPoojaSen20
 
ICT Role in 21st Century Education & its Challenges.pptx
ICT Role in 21st Century Education & its Challenges.pptxICT Role in 21st Century Education & its Challenges.pptx
ICT Role in 21st Century Education & its Challenges.pptxAreebaZafar22
 
Python Notes for mca i year students osmania university.docx
Python Notes for mca i year students osmania university.docxPython Notes for mca i year students osmania university.docx
Python Notes for mca i year students osmania university.docxRamakrishna Reddy Bijjam
 
1029-Danh muc Sach Giao Khoa khoi 6.pdf
1029-Danh muc Sach Giao Khoa khoi  6.pdf1029-Danh muc Sach Giao Khoa khoi  6.pdf
1029-Danh muc Sach Giao Khoa khoi 6.pdfQucHHunhnh
 

Recently uploaded (20)

Unit-IV- Pharma. Marketing Channels.pptx
Unit-IV- Pharma. Marketing Channels.pptxUnit-IV- Pharma. Marketing Channels.pptx
Unit-IV- Pharma. Marketing Channels.pptx
 
Grant Readiness 101 TechSoup and Remy Consulting
Grant Readiness 101 TechSoup and Remy ConsultingGrant Readiness 101 TechSoup and Remy Consulting
Grant Readiness 101 TechSoup and Remy Consulting
 
1029 - Danh muc Sach Giao Khoa 10 . pdf
1029 -  Danh muc Sach Giao Khoa 10 . pdf1029 -  Danh muc Sach Giao Khoa 10 . pdf
1029 - Danh muc Sach Giao Khoa 10 . pdf
 
Micro-Scholarship, What it is, How can it help me.pdf
Micro-Scholarship, What it is, How can it help me.pdfMicro-Scholarship, What it is, How can it help me.pdf
Micro-Scholarship, What it is, How can it help me.pdf
 
Kodo Millet PPT made by Ghanshyam bairwa college of Agriculture kumher bhara...
Kodo Millet  PPT made by Ghanshyam bairwa college of Agriculture kumher bhara...Kodo Millet  PPT made by Ghanshyam bairwa college of Agriculture kumher bhara...
Kodo Millet PPT made by Ghanshyam bairwa college of Agriculture kumher bhara...
 
Explore beautiful and ugly buildings. Mathematics helps us create beautiful d...
Explore beautiful and ugly buildings. Mathematics helps us create beautiful d...Explore beautiful and ugly buildings. Mathematics helps us create beautiful d...
Explore beautiful and ugly buildings. Mathematics helps us create beautiful d...
 
Seal of Good Local Governance (SGLG) 2024Final.pptx
Seal of Good Local Governance (SGLG) 2024Final.pptxSeal of Good Local Governance (SGLG) 2024Final.pptx
Seal of Good Local Governance (SGLG) 2024Final.pptx
 
Key note speaker Neum_Admir Softic_ENG.pdf
Key note speaker Neum_Admir Softic_ENG.pdfKey note speaker Neum_Admir Softic_ENG.pdf
Key note speaker Neum_Admir Softic_ENG.pdf
 
Jual Obat Aborsi Hongkong ( Asli No.1 ) 085657271886 Obat Penggugur Kandungan...
Jual Obat Aborsi Hongkong ( Asli No.1 ) 085657271886 Obat Penggugur Kandungan...Jual Obat Aborsi Hongkong ( Asli No.1 ) 085657271886 Obat Penggugur Kandungan...
Jual Obat Aborsi Hongkong ( Asli No.1 ) 085657271886 Obat Penggugur Kandungan...
 
Russian Escort Service in Delhi 11k Hotel Foreigner Russian Call Girls in Delhi
Russian Escort Service in Delhi 11k Hotel Foreigner Russian Call Girls in DelhiRussian Escort Service in Delhi 11k Hotel Foreigner Russian Call Girls in Delhi
Russian Escort Service in Delhi 11k Hotel Foreigner Russian Call Girls in Delhi
 
How to Create and Manage Wizard in Odoo 17
How to Create and Manage Wizard in Odoo 17How to Create and Manage Wizard in Odoo 17
How to Create and Manage Wizard in Odoo 17
 
Food safety_Challenges food safety laboratories_.pdf
Food safety_Challenges food safety laboratories_.pdfFood safety_Challenges food safety laboratories_.pdf
Food safety_Challenges food safety laboratories_.pdf
 
Unit-IV; Professional Sales Representative (PSR).pptx
Unit-IV; Professional Sales Representative (PSR).pptxUnit-IV; Professional Sales Representative (PSR).pptx
Unit-IV; Professional Sales Representative (PSR).pptx
 
Holdier Curriculum Vitae (April 2024).pdf
Holdier Curriculum Vitae (April 2024).pdfHoldier Curriculum Vitae (April 2024).pdf
Holdier Curriculum Vitae (April 2024).pdf
 
Application orientated numerical on hev.ppt
Application orientated numerical on hev.pptApplication orientated numerical on hev.ppt
Application orientated numerical on hev.ppt
 
SKILL OF INTRODUCING THE LESSON MICRO SKILLS.pptx
SKILL OF INTRODUCING THE LESSON MICRO SKILLS.pptxSKILL OF INTRODUCING THE LESSON MICRO SKILLS.pptx
SKILL OF INTRODUCING THE LESSON MICRO SKILLS.pptx
 
psychiatric nursing HISTORY COLLECTION .docx
psychiatric  nursing HISTORY  COLLECTION  .docxpsychiatric  nursing HISTORY  COLLECTION  .docx
psychiatric nursing HISTORY COLLECTION .docx
 
ICT Role in 21st Century Education & its Challenges.pptx
ICT Role in 21st Century Education & its Challenges.pptxICT Role in 21st Century Education & its Challenges.pptx
ICT Role in 21st Century Education & its Challenges.pptx
 
Python Notes for mca i year students osmania university.docx
Python Notes for mca i year students osmania university.docxPython Notes for mca i year students osmania university.docx
Python Notes for mca i year students osmania university.docx
 
1029-Danh muc Sach Giao Khoa khoi 6.pdf
1029-Danh muc Sach Giao Khoa khoi  6.pdf1029-Danh muc Sach Giao Khoa khoi  6.pdf
1029-Danh muc Sach Giao Khoa khoi 6.pdf
 

Is Marijuana a Gateway DrugAuthor(s) Jeffrey DeSimoneSou.docx

  • 1. Is Marijuana a Gateway Drug? Author(s): Jeffrey DeSimone Source: Eastern Economic Journal, Vol. 24, No. 2 (Spring, 1998), pp. 149-164 Published by: Palgrave Macmillan Journals Stable URL: http://www.jstor.org/stable/40325834 . Accessed: 18/11/2014 03:18 Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available at . http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp . JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide range of content in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and facilitate new forms of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact [email protected] . Palgrave Macmillan Journals is collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend access to Eastern Economic Journal. http://www.jstor.org This content downloaded from 130.166.3.5 on Tue, 18 Nov 2014 03:18:48 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
  • 2. http://www.jstor.org/action/showPublisher?publisherCode=pal http://www.jstor.org/stable/40325834?origin=JSTOR-pdf http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp IS MARIJUANA A GATEWAY DRUG? Jeffrey DeSimone Yale University INTRODUCTION Marijuana is by far the most widely-used illicit drug. Though marijuana is a pow- erful intoxicant with subjective psychedelic-like effects that are more complicated than those of alcohol or cocaine, research has yet to show that marijuana consump- tion has harmful consequences. In truth, the primary cause for concern about mari- juana use may be that it potentially leads to the use of more hazardous illegal drugs such as cocaine. This premise arises from evidence that the overwhelming majority of adolescent and young adult cocaine users have previously used marijuana [O'Donnell and Clayton, 1982; Mills and Noyes, 1984; Yamaguchi and Kandel, 1984; Newcomb and Bentler, 1986; Kandel and Yamaguchi, 1993] and is known as the gateway hy- pothesis. Since the use of cocaine is associated with problems such as crime, child poverty, poor neonatal health, and the spread of HIV, a gateway effect of marijuana
  • 3. on cocaine could signify a sizable social cost of marijuana use. Prior marijuana consumption may, however, predict current cocaine consump- tion without necessarily causing it. Marijuana use may simply be a marker of either observable personal characteristics or unobservable factors that make marijuana us- ers more likely to progress to cocaine use [Kleiman, 1992]. Conversely, marijuana may truly act as a gateway to cocaine in two fashions. Marijuana intoxication may spawn curiosity or diminish apprehension about trying more dangerous drugs. Or, the physiological and psychological benefits, say "euphoria" (from Stigler and Becker [1977]), induced by a certain level of marijuana consumption may decline over time, thereby prompting users to experiment with new drugs in an attempt to regain their original levels of euphoria [Kleiman, 1992]. The latter process above can be explained in terms of the economic model of ad- diction as specified by Becker and Murphy [1988] and Chaloupka [1991]. In this model, the cumulative past consumption of an addictive good represents an "addictive stock" that raises current consumption by creating both tolerance, through a negative mar- ginal utility, and reinforcement, through a positive effect on the marginal utility of current consumption. Grossman et al. [1996a] and Pacula [1997] find that marijuana is addictive in the sense that past use raises the likelihood of current use. Addictive
  • 4. marijuana can generate a gateway effect in two distinct ways. One is simply through contemporaneous complementarity of marijuana and cocaine. The other is through a direct positive effect of past marijuana consumption on the marginal utility of current Eastern Economic Journal, Vol. 24, No. 2, Spring 1998 149 This content downloaded from 130.166.3.5 on Tue, 18 Nov 2014 03:18:48 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp 150 EASTERN ECONOMIC JOURNAL consumption of other euphoria-producing goods such as cocaine, which may occur because the addictive stock is not of marijuana itself but rather of the euphoria pro- duced by marijuana. In this case, marijuana could conceivably serve both as a gate- way to cocaine and as a substitute to cocaine in the production of euphoria [Kleiman, 1992]. Evidence of negative cross-price effects between the two drugs, as reported by DeSimone [1997], Grossman et al. [1996b] and Saffer and Chaloupka [1996], implies contemporaneous complementarity but is also consistent with a direct intertemporal relationship because none of these studies disentangles past and current price ef-
  • 5. fects. In combination, then, the empirical findings of addictive marijuana and negative cross-price effects suggest a gateway effect of marijuana on cocaine. Notwithstand- ing, no formal econometric evidence of the intertemporal relationship between the two drugs has been obtained to this point. This paper provides such evidence using data from the National Longitudinal Survey of Youth (NLSY). Though the study does not attempt to identify the causal mechanisms by which marijuana and cocaine are related, it is the first to estimate a structural effect of past marijuana demand on current cocaine demand. The results provide strong confirmation of the gateway hy- pothesis. EMPIRICAL SPECIFICATION To econometrically test the gateway hypothesis, the current demand for cocaine must be estimated, for a sample of individuals who have not previously used cocaine, as a function of past marijuana demand and current values of other variables that influence cocaine use. Using the subscript t to denote the current period and t -k to denote the period k years in the past, current cocaine consumption Ct is thus repre- sented as a function of past marijuana consumption Mt_k and a vector Xt of additional exogenous determinants,
  • 6. (1) Ct=b0 + btMt.h + b2Xt + e, A gateway effect exists if b1 > 0 in equation (1). Two empirical considerations make ordinary least squares (OLS) estimation of equation (1) inappropriate. First, marijuana use is a function of many of the same variables that determine cocaine use.1 Although OLS on equation (1) holds Mt_k con- stant while estimating the direct effect of variables in Xt, some components of Xt may concurrently affect Ct indirectly through Mt_k. More importantly, Mt_k and Ct may be spuriously correlated because of unobserved factors that simultaneously affect the use of both types of drugs. For instance, tastes for intoxication or deviance are likely to vary positively with both marijuana and cocaine use. Meanwhile, other unobserved factors may lead individuals to choose one drug over the other as a producer of eupho- ria. Since all previous users of cocaine are excluded from the estimation sample, unobservables may in this situation reflect a preference for marijuana over cocaine in period t -k because marijuana is less costly, less dangerous, less stigmatized and more easily obtained. The regression assumption that Mt_k and ec are uncorrelated may This content downloaded from 130.166.3.5 on Tue, 18 Nov 2014 03:18:48 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp
  • 7. IS MARIJUANA A GATEWAY DRUG? 15 1 thus be violated, resulting in bias and inconsistency in the OLS estimates of the pa- rameters of equation (1). To account for the potential correlation between Mt_h and cc, a two-stage instru- mental variable (IV) regression procedure is employed. The first stage equation rep- resents past marijuana demand as a function of the exogenous variables Xt that affect current cocaine demand and a vector Zt_k of variables that affect past marijuana de- mand but not current cocaine demand, (2) Mt_k = a0 + a2 X, + a2 Zt_k + em. In theory the lagged values of X also belong on the right-hand side of equation (2), but are omitted from the empirical analysis because the variables in X are either time- invariant or highly correlated over time.2 Then, since the predicted value of Mt_k in equation (2) represents the component of Mt_k that is uncorrelated with the unobserv- able factors ec that impact Ct, equation (1) is typically estimated using this predicted value of Mt_k as a regressor in place of the observed Mt_k. The second empirical concern is that Ct andMt_A are specified as binary indicators of drug use, since the gateway hypothesis posits a relationship between the use, rather
  • 8. than explicit quantities of consumption, of each drug.3 Because Ct is binary, equation (I) is most suitably estimated with a probit model. Smith and Blundell [1986] and Blundell and Smith [1989] show that equation (1) is consistently estimated with a probit that uses the observed value ofM^ but also includes the residual term em from equation (2), (II) Ct = b0 + b1Muk + b2Xt + b3em + ec. These studies also derive the expression for the correct asymptotic covariance matrix for the probit estimates of equation (I1). A limitation of this procedure is its assump- tion that the included endogenous variable, in this caseMt_ki is fully observed. Equa- tion (2) must therefore be estimated as a linear probability model. In order to correct for heteroskedasticity, equation (2) is first estimated by OLS to obtain predicted val- ues of Mt_k, and then reestimated by weighted least squares using the inverse of these predicted values as weights [Gujarati, 1995]. To improve on OLS, the set of instrumental variables Zt_k that is excluded from the cocaine demand equation must be highly correlated with Mt_k but uncorrelated with ec [Gujarati, 1995]. As is well known, nonzero correlation of Zt_k and ec will ren- der the IV estimates of equation (1) inconsistent. Moreover, Bound et al. [1995] illus- trates that the explanatory power of Zt_k is crucial for two reasons. First, if Zt_k is only
  • 9. weakly correlated with Mt_k, then even a weak correlation between Z<jk and ec can produce a large inconsistency in the IV estimates of equation (1) that may even sur- pass that of the OLS estimates. Second, IV estimates are biased in finite samples, and the magnitude of this bias approaches that of OLS as the explanatory power of Zt_k approaches zero. These empirical considerations must guide the choice of Zt_k in the analysis. This content downloaded from 130.166.3.5 on Tue, 18 Nov 2014 03:18:48 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp 152 EASTERN ECONOMIC JOURNAL DATA The primary source of data is the NLSY [Center for Human Resource Research, 1995]. Since 1979, the NLSY annually has collected detailed demographic and eco- nomic information from a cohort of 12,686 individuals originally aged between 14 and 22. In the 1984 and 1988 interviews, respondents were asked about their current and lifetime use of a variety of drugs, including marijuana and cocaine. Consequently, the relationship between cocaine demand in t=1988 and the demand for marijuana k=4 years previously is estimated for respondents who report no
  • 10. previous lifetime use of cocaine in 1984. Past year rather than lifetime measures of drug use are employed in an attempt to restrict attention to individuals who are persistent rather than experi- mental drug users, following the interpretation of Saffer and Chaloupka [1996] that annual participation reflects at least occasional use. The estimate here thus mea- sures the gateway from recurrent marijuana to cocaine use, which is more relevant for drug policy than one that also encompasses experimental drug use. As mentioned earlier, the drug use variables are binary indicators of consumption. Note that NLSY respondents are between 23 and 31 years old in 1988, an impor- tant consideration since all existing evidence of a marijuana gateway comes based upon responses from individuals in their teens and early twenties. A specific concern is that the sample is highly selective because cocaine initiation declines with age in the NLSY. More precisely, even though only 17 percent of the respondents inter- viewed in 1984 had previously used cocaine and are thus excluded from the sample, this group is almost four times as large as the number of respondents in the sample reporting past year use in 1988. The estimate of the gateway effect reported here, therefore, may not hold at younger ages or for the population in general. In particu- lar, given that past year marijuana prevalence in the NLSY also fell over time, from
  • 11. 46 percent in 1980 to 32 percent in 1984, a gateway effect may not be detectable because precisely those individuals for whom the effect is likely to be strongest are not included in the sample.4 On the other hand, the finding of a gateway effect would mark an extension of the age range within which the phenomenon is considered to be consequential. The set of explanatory variables included in the vector X^ is as follows. Race is represented by indicators of black and Hispanic ethnicity. Educational attainment measures human capital and is expected to be negatively correlated with drug de- mand, as is age and marriage. Males traditionally have higher rates of drug use than females. Indicators of living in a central city and in an SMSA outside a central city control for the possibility of increased availability of illegal drugs in urban areas. Indicators of a Catholic or nonreligious upbringing may reflect the presence or ab- sence of anti-drug values and attitudes. An indicator of the presence of both parents in the household at age fourteen is intended to capture parental supervision and may further capture family values that discourage drug use. Past year earnings will be positively associated with drug demand if drugs are normal goods.6 In addition, esti- mates of the average past year retail price of one pure gram of cocaine, imputed for over 140 cities using data from the Drug Enforcement Administration (DEA) on pur-
  • 12. chases made by undercover agents from 1977 to 1994, are matched to the individual This content downloaded from 130.166.3.5 on Tue, 18 Nov 2014 03:18:48 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp IS MARIJUANA A GATEWAY DRUG? 153 NLSY responses.6 As previously mentioned, values of all time- varying variables are taken from the 1988, or current period, interview. The set of instruments 7*M that identify marijuana use includes two measures of state-level penalties for marijuana possession and two additional variables that are expected to affect marijuana use through their influence on alcohol consumption. The marijuana penalty variables, which pertain to the possession of one ounce of mari- juana for first-time offenders in the state of residence of the respondent in 1984, are the maximum prison term and an indicator that fines are not assessed. Both of these variables are components of the expected cost of marijuana use and as such contrib- ute to the full price of marijuana.7 The expected cost of marijuana use, in terms of time, lost wages and stigma from being arrested and sent to prison, rises as the maxi- mum prison term increases from zero in ten states to a year in eighteen states and
  • 13. more than that in six others. Similarly, the expected monetary cost is lower in the two states, Massachusetts and Oklahoma, in which no fine can be levied compared to other states in which the maximum fine ranges from $100 (in ten states) to $2,500 or more (in seven states).8 The alcohol-related variables are the state excise tax on beer and an indicator of parental alcoholism or problem drinking. The beer tax is the tax on a case of 24 twelve-ounce beers containing 3.2 percent alcohol [Beer Institute, 1995]. If marijuana and alcohol are substitutes, as reported by DiNardo and Lemieux [1992], Model [1993] and Chaloupka and Laixuthai [1994], then marijuana demand will respond positively to increases in the beer tax, though Saffer and Chaloupka [1996] find evidence of the reverse relationship. Meanwhile, Cadoret [1992] and Merikangas et al. [1992] report an association between parental alcohol problems and filial drug use. This relationship may operate through alcohol use, since the pre- viously cited research on the chronological path of drug initiation shows that alcohol use almost always precedes the initiation of illegal drug use, while Kenkel and Ribar [1994] find that children of parents with alcohol problems are more likely to consume alcohol than others. Although marijuana penalties could conceivably influence cocaine and marijuana use separately if they reflect sentiments towards illegal drug use in general [Model,
  • 14. 1993], the exclusion of the two marijuana penalty variables from the cocaine demand equation is natural because their direct impact is on marijuana demand. However, the exclusion of the two alcohol-related variables is more questionable. The rationale is the expectation that the consumption of alcohol is more closely related with that of marijuana than that of other illegal drugs like cocaine that are more dangerous and less socially acceptable. Besides evidence that alcohol use usually precedes the initia- tion of marijuana use even for the large fraction of marijuana users who do not progress to cocaine use, additional support for this exclusion strategy is given by Mills and Noyes [1984], Yamaguchi and Kandel [1984] and Newcomb and Bentler [1986], who fail to find a direct connection between past alcohol and current cocaine use. Never- theless, the propriety of this restriction and the full set of exclusions is empirically tested below, as is the power of the marijuana penalty variables and the full set of excluded instruments Z^ to explain the variation in marijuana use. This content downloaded from 130.166.3.5 on Tue, 18 Nov 2014 03:18:48 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp 154 EASTERN ECONOMIC JOURNAL
  • 15. TABLE 1 Descriptive Statistics (n=7,279) Standard Mean Deviation Dependent Variables Used Cocaine Past Year 0.057 0.232 Used Marijuana Past Year (in 1984) 0.246 0.431 Explanatory Variables Age 27.005 2.265 Education 12.683 2.437 Male 0.443 0.497 Black 0.270 0.444 Hispanic 0.162 0.368 Married 0.482 0.500 Central City Residence 0.143 0.350 SMSA Residence 0.595 0.491 Catholic Background 0.323 0.468 No Religious Background 0.039 0.193 Earnings Past Year (in 1000s) 17.663 15.111 Cocaine Price 123.620 30.144 Both Parents Present Age 14 0.691 0.462 Excluded Instrumental Variables Alcoholic Parent 0.215 0.411 Beer Tax (in 1984) 0.540 0.621 Maximum Jail Time for Marijuana (in 1984) 0.775 1.269 No Fine for Marijuana (in 1984) 0.036 0.187 Table 1 presents the means and standard deviations of the variables included in the analysis for the 7,279 respondents with complete data.9
  • 16. Almost a quarter of the sample used marijuana in the year prior to the 1984 interview, but fewer than 6 percent used cocaine in the year preceding the 1988 interview. Table 2 exhibits the joint frequency of past marijuana and current cocaine demand. Even though 1984 marijuana nonusers outnumber users by a three-to-one margin, almost two-thirds of those who consumed cocaine in 1988 also consumed marijuana in 1984. A chi-square test of independence formally rejects the hypothesis that marijuana users are no more likely than nonusers to progress to cocaine use. However, more rigorous examination is necessary to determine whether this preliminary evidence of a gateway effect actu- ally represents a causal relationship. A final point before proceeding to the regression results is that since drug use is an illegal activity, it may be underreported by NLSY respondents. Some evidence of underreporting exists for lifetime cocaine use in 1984 [Mensch and Kandel, 1988] and for both lifetime and past month marijuana and cocaine use, in both 1984 and 1988, in the modest (around 9 percent) fraction of interviews in which parents are present This content downloaded from 130.166.3.5 on Tue, 18 Nov 2014 03:18:48 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp
  • 17. IS MARIJUANA A GATEWAY DRUG? 155 TABLE 2 Joint Frequencies of Marijuana and Cocaine Use Used Cocaine Past Year 1988 Yes No Total Used Marijuana Past Year 1984 Yes 270 1522 1792 No 147 5340 5487 Total 417 6862 7279 Chi-Squared Test of Independence: 2(1) = 383.8, p = 0.000 or that take place over the telephone [Hoyt and Chaloupka, 1994]. However, Sickles and Taubman [1991] provide evidence that reported past year drug use should be fairly accurate in both years. Furthermore, as long as marijuana use is truthfully reported, underreporting of 1988 cocaine use will only bias the estimate of the gate- way effect if this underreporting is correlated with 1984 marijuana use. But if the strong association between marijuana and cocaine use recorded in Table 2 also holds for cocaine users who report not using cocaine, so that marijuana users are more likely than nonusers to underreport cocaine, then the effect of underreporting of 1988 cocaine use but not 1984 marijuana use is to bias the estimated gateway coefficient towards zero.10 Such downward bias is exacerbated if lifetime cocaine use in 1984 is
  • 18. also underreported, as suggested by evidence from Johnston et al. [1988] that respon- dents who lie do so consistently over time, because the primary effect of underreporting in this case is to count respondents as current cocaine nonusers when in fact they should be excluded from the sample.11 RESULTS Table 3 displays the regression results. Column 1 shows the estimates of equation (2), the first stage equation for marijuana use in 1984. The variables of primary con- cern are the excluded instruments Z^. The signs are as anticipated for the three of these variables for which prior expectations of the sign exist. The predicted likelihood of marijuana use is 3 percent lower in Nevada, which has the highest maximum prison term of six years, than in the ten states in which first-time marijuana possession offenses carry no prison sentence. The coefficient approaches statistical significance with ap-value of 0.136. The remaining three identifying instruments are statistically significant at all conventional confidence levels. Having an alcoholic parent increases the probability of marijuana consumption slightly more than living in a state with no fines for first-time marijuana possession. Meanwhile, the coefficient of the beer tax predicts that marijuana consumption is over 4 percent more probable in Wyoming, which has the lowest beer tax of $0.04, than in Alabama, which has the highest of
  • 19. $2.28. Although this evidence of complementarity between alcohol and marijuana contradicts the findings of DiNardo and Lemieux [1992], Model [1993] and Chaloupka and Laixuthai [1994], this result may not generalize because of the selection of the sample used here. This content downloaded from 130.166.3.5 on Tue, 18 Nov 2014 03:18:48 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp 156 EASTERN ECONOMIC JOURNAL TABLE 3 Equations for Past Year Drug Demand First Stage: Second Stage: WLS for 1984 Probits for 1988 Marijuana Use Cocaine Use 0) Í2a) Í2b) Constant 0.422a 0.108b 0.177 (0.066) (0.054) (0.200) Marijuana Use (in 1984) 0.292a 0.226 (0.074) (0.176) Age -0.006a -0.0017 -0.0022 (0.002) (0.0012) (0.0015) Education -0.001 -0.0028b -0.0028b
  • 20. (0.002) (0.0011) (0.0011) Male 0.114a -0.006 0.002 (0.010) (0.009) (0.021) Black -0.015 -0.011 -0.012c (0.012) (0.007) (0.007) Hispanic -0.088a 0.002 -0.004 (0.015) (0.011) (0.017) Married -0.070a -0.020b -0.024c (0.012) (0.008) (0.014) Central City Residence 0.071a 0.0001 0.006 (0.017) (0.010) (0.015) SMSA Residence 0.079a -0.006 -0.000003 (0.011) (0.009) (0.015) Catholic Background 0.041a -0.001 0.002 (0.013) (0.007) (0.009) No Religious Background 0.075a -0.025c -0.020 (0.028) (0.014) (0.018) Earnings Past Year -0.0011a 0.0004c 0.0003 (in 1000s) (0.0003) (0.0002) (0.0003) Cocaine Price -0.206 -0.184b -0.199b (in 1000s) (0.163) (0.093) (0.091) Both Parents Present -0.015 0.001 0.0004 Age 14 (0.011) (0.006) (0.006) Alcoholic Parent 0.065a 0.007
  • 21. (0.013) (0.013) Beer Tax (in 1984) -0.019a 0.001 (0.007) (0.006) Maximum Jail Time for Marijuana -0.0053 (in 1984) (0.0036) No Fine for Marijuana 0.057a (in 1984) (0.018) Standard deviations are given in parentheses. In columns 2a and 2b, the constant indicates the probabil- ity of cocaine use when all variables are set to zero, while remaining coefficients represent the change in probability of cocaine use for a unit change in the explanatory variable while holding all other variables constant at their mean values. a. Significant at the 0.01 level. b. Significant at the 0.05 level. c. Significant at the 0.10 level. This content downloaded from 130.166.3.5 on Tue, 18 Nov 2014 03:18:48 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp IS MARIJUANA A GATEWAY DRUG? 157 Of the other explanatory variables, those of greatest economic relevance are earn- ings and the price of cocaine. The results for these two variables contradict, to a great extent, evidence from Grossman et al. [1996a; 1996b] and
  • 22. Saffer and Chaloupka [1996] that marijuana is a normal good that is complementary with cocaine. Though the cocaine price does carry a negative coefficient, its effect is statistically insignificant. Moreover, the effect of earnings is negative and significant. An interpretation of these results, though, must consider the construction of the sample. As cocaine becomes more expensive, some respondents who would otherwise have initiated cocaine and therefore been excluded from the sample may instead substitute toward marijuana rather than away from illegal drugs altogether, contributing to the insignificance of the cocaine price. The same may occur as earnings declines, since the large expense of cocaine per dose may imply a large income effect. It does not necessarily follow that marijuana and cocaine use are unrelated, nor that marijuana is an inferior good, for the general population that also includes cocaine users. The only other surprising result is the significantly higher likelihood of use for Catholics, which again may be an artifact of the sample selection procedure if Catholic drug users are more inclined to use marijuana than cocaine as a producer of euphoria. The remaining explanatory variables have the expected relationship with marijuana consumption, and all are significant besides educational attainment, black racial status, and the presence of both parents in the household at age fourteen. Column 2a of Table 3 gives the results for equation (I1), the
  • 23. second stage probit for 1988 cocaine demand. As previously discussed, past marijuana use is identified through the exclusion of both the two marijuana penalty variables and the two alcohol-related variables. The coefficients are reported in terms of the change in probability of co- caine use induced by a unit change in the explanatory variable while holding all other variables constant at their mean values, while the constant represents the probabil- ity of cocaine use when all variables equal zero. The crucial result, of course, is the statistically significant and extremely large positive effect of past marijuana use. In particular, past marijuana use raises the probability of consuming cocaine by more than 29 percentage points. This impact is clearly substantial, dwarfing that of the other explanatory variables, for realistic variations in their values, by a factor of at least ten. Not only is a strong gateway effect of marijuana on cocaine apparent, there- fore, but it is by far the most important factor in explaining current cocaine demand. The relevance of economic factors is shown by the fact that besides earnings and the price of cocaine, only three other exogenous variables in column 2a are signifi- cant. The coefficients of the earnings and price variables indicate, in agreement with findings of Grossman et al. [1996b] and Saffer and Chaloupka [1996], that cocaine is a normal good with a downward-sloping demand curve. The magnitudes of these ef-
  • 24. fects, however, are modest. An increase in earnings of one standard deviation, or $15,000, raises the probability of using cocaine by just over half a percentage point, which is almost identical to the impact of lowering the price of cocaine by one stan- dard deviation, or $30. The implied price elasticity of -0.40 is, nonetheless, consis- tent with that estimated in the studies mentioned above. Meanwhile, the other sig- nificant results indicate that four additional years of education, marriage, and an This content downloaded from 130.166.3.5 on Tue, 18 Nov 2014 03:18:48 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp 158 EASTERN ECONOMIC JOURNAL TABLE 4 Specification Tests for Cocaine Use Probits Model (a) Model (b) First Stage F-statistic for Excluded Instruments 12.84 6.25 (0.000) (0.002) Overidentification Test x2-statistic 1.577 0.523 (0.816) (0.770) Second Stage x2-statistic for Alcohol Variables - 0.83 (0.660)
  • 25. Hausman Test t-statistic 0.231a 0.164 (0.060) (0.152) Hausman Test for (a) vs (b) - 0.067 (0.140) Models (a) and (b) correspond to columns 2a and 2b, respectively, of Table 3. P-values are given in parentheses beneath F and x2-statistics, while standard deviations are given in parentheses beneath t- statistics. a. Significant at the .01 level. upbringing that involves religion lowers the probability of using cocaine by 1, 2, and 2.5 percentage points, respectively. Again, though, the most notable characteristic of the significant coefficients is that their magnitudes are trivial in comparison with that of past marijuana use. Table 4 reports the results of various tests regarding the specification of the IV procedure. The test statistics in column a correspond to the model of column 2a in Table 3. In the top row, the joint F-statistic for the excluded instruments Z^ verifies that these variables are highly correlated with marijuana demand, an essential con- dition for minimizing the standard errors of the IV estimates. Consequently, any inconsistency in the IV estimates arising from a weak nonzero correlation between Z^ and ec should be low relative to that of OLS. Following Bound et al. [1995], this F- statistic also implies that the inherent small sample bias in the
  • 26. IV estimates is only about 1 IF, or 8 percent, of the bias arising from OLS estimation. The next row gives the statistic for a test of the validity of the overidentifying restrictions. If ZM is jointly correlated with ec and therefore should in reality be in- cluded in equation (I1), then the IV estimates of equation (I1) are inconsistent. Lee [1991] illustrates how a chi-square test statistic for the overidentifying restrictions, with degrees of freedom equal to the number of excluded instruments, can be ob- tained as a by-product of the IV regression methodology because, as Blundell and Smith [1989] show, the estimation procedure is a minimum chi- square method. The joint hypothesis that the excluded instruments neither belong in the second stage equation (I1) nor are correlated with the second stage residuals ec cannot be rejected at standard significance levels. More precisely, the extremely high p-value provides evidence that any correlation between Zw and ec is quite weak. This content downloaded from 130.166.3.5 on Tue, 18 Nov 2014 03:18:48 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp IS MARIJUANA A GATEWAY DRUG? 159 The remaining statistic in column a of Table 4, appearing in the
  • 27. fourth row, is for a test of the exogeneity of past marijuana use in equation (I1). As Smith and Blundell [1986] show, the t-statistic for the coefficient of the first stage residual em, b3, in equa- tion (I1) provides an exogeneity test that is analogous to the standard Hausman test for exogeneity [Hausman, 1978]. Since the IV procedure is correctly specified, as the F and overidentification tests verify, any difference in the IV and OLS estimates of bv the gateway effect, arises because a nonzero correlation between Mw and ec affects the OLS but not the IV estimate. The exogeneity test statistic measures the magni- tude of this difference and thus indicates an OLS estimate of 0.061. Since the IV estimate is significantly larger than the OLS estimate, the latter must exhibit down- ward bias. This bias has two potential causes: observable factors that in reality affect cocaine use in part through marijuana use, and unobservable factors that increase past marijuana demand while decreasing current cocaine demand. To disentangle these two sources of bias, I evaluate the IV estimates of the co- caine demand equation (I1) at mean values of the explanatory variables for marijuana users and nonusers (not reported here) while holding marijuana use constant and take the difference in predicted cocaine use between users and nonusers. I then do the same for the OLS estimates of equation (I1) (also not reported here). The differ-
  • 28. ence between these two quantities reveals that only 1.5 percentage points of the dis- crepancy between the IV and OLS estimates of the gateway effect represent effects of exogenous explanatory variables that in reality work through past marijuana use, but are incorrectly attributed by OLS to the variables themselves. Unobserved het- erogeneity must account for the remainder of the difference between the IV and OLS coefficients. More precisely, unobserved factors make marijuana users 21.6 percent- age points less likely than nonusers to consume cocaine. Unlike OLS, the IV method- ology is able to separate this unobserved heterogeneity from the true causal effect of marijuana use. This finding contradicts the conventional wisdom that the gateway effect is an artifact of unobserved variables that make both marijuana and cocaine consumption more likely, suggesting instead that unobserved substitutability of mari- juana and cocaine use masks an even greater effect of marijuana use than the OLS estimate of the gateway effect indicates. This result is not inconsistent with intertemporal complementarity of marijuana and cocaine use. It simply implies that marijuana users have actively chosen marijuana over cocaine as a producer of eupho- ria. The unobserved reasons for this choice make them, ceterisparibus, less likely to progress to cocaine use than others who have never used cocaine, even though these others may have been more likely to avoid illegal drugs altogether. Ironically, mari-
  • 29. juana users are subsequently more likely to use cocaine because of the substantial effect of marijuana use itself. The variables in Z^ most likely to belong in the second stage equation (I1) are the alcoholic parent indicator and the beer tax. To further evaluate the validity of exclud- ing these two variables, I directly compare the specification discussed so far to an alternative specification in which these variables are included in equation (I1). Col- umn 2b of Table 3 shows the estimates of this alternative model. Not surprisingly, the effects of the exogenous variables are quite similar across the two IV equations. In This content downloaded from 130.166.3.5 on Tue, 18 Nov 2014 03:18:48 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp 160 EASTERN ECONOMIC JOURNAL addition, the estimated gateway effect in column 2b is much closer to that of column 2a than that of OLS. Because the standard error is more than twice as large as that in 2a, though, the estimate in 2b is not significantly different from zero and hence yields a much different implication than does the estimate in 2a. Column b of Table 4 displays the results of the relevant specification tests for the
  • 30. model presented in column 2b of Table 3, allowing investigation of the sources of the variation between the two IV estimates of the gateway effect. The top two rows verify that this alternative model is also validly specified. The relative magnitudes of the F- statistics in columns a and b imply that the gateway estimate in column 2b of Table 3 will exhibit greater small sample bias than that in column 2a. It is thus expected that, as Table 3 indicates, the estimate in column 2b is closer to the OLS estimate than is that in column 2a. Meanwhile, the third row shows that the two alcohol-related vari- ables are jointly insignificant in the cocaine demand equation, which is not surprising given that neither individually approaches significance in Table 3. This result pro- vides explicit evidence that the two alcohol variables are validly excluded from the cocaine demand equation, which supports the more general conclusion from the col- umn a overidentification test statistic that the full exclusion restriction is valid. Fi- nally, the bottom two rows report the statistics for the exogeneity tests that compare the gateway coefficient in this model to those of the OLS and column a models, re- spectively. Though the model a estimate is significantly different from the OLS esti- mate, the estimate of this model is not significantly different from those of either column a or OLS because of the large standard error. The combined results of the specification tests indicate that the primary conse-
  • 31. quence of the exclusion of the two alcohol-related variables from the cocaine demand equation is an increase in efficiency of the IV estimate of the gateway effect. Since these variables are highly related to past marijuana consumption but not separately related to current cocaine consumption, their exclusion does not alter the magnitude of the estimate of the gateway effect, but does provide the additional explanatory power necessary to reduce the standard errors enough to produce statistical signifi- cance. Furthermore, the evidence that alcohol use leads to cocaine use only through its strong complementarity with marijuana use is consistent with the hypothesis that a separate intertemporal link from alcohol to marijuana precedes the one from mari- juana to cocaine that is shown here. CONCLUSION This study has found evidence of a gateway from marijuana to cocaine that takes place at later ages than were previously thought relevant. Structural estimates ac- counting for unobserved heterogeneity that affects both marijuana and cocaine de- mand indicate that past marijuana use increases the probability of current cocaine use by twenty-nine percentage points. This effect is nearly three times as large as the one-in-ten increase that Kleiman [1992] cites as warranting a considerable expansion in efforts to control marijuana use. To put the magnitude of this result in perspective,
  • 32. preventing past marijuana use decreases the likelihood of cocaine initiation by an amount that is almost thirteen times greater than that brought about by a doubling This content downloaded from 130.166.3.5 on Tue, 18 Nov 2014 03:18:48 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp IS MARIJUANA A GATEWAY DRUG? 161 of the average cocaine price, which any feasible enforcement effort is unlikely to ac- complish [Kleiman, 1992]. In order to most effectively deter cocaine use, therefore, some resources devoted to raising prices, which is the predominant focus of present U.S. drug policy, should be redirected towards the prevention of marijuana initiation by adolescents and young adults. As a caveat, the estimate of the gateway effect obtained here suffers from several potential deficiencies as a result of data limitations. First, current and past drug use are crudely measured with a longtime interval between the two periods. Consequently, questions remain regarding the extent and persistence of marijuana use necessary to bring about cocaine use and the length of time between marijuana and cocaine initia- tion. Second, the gateway effect may be less pronounced for younger cocaine users
  • 33. who were excluded from the sample employed here. Earlier cocaine use may reflect a stronger inclination towards cocaine that makes it less likely to be preceded by mari- juana use. In addition, the unobserved factors found here to bias the OLS estimate towards zero may be an artifact of the substitution away from cocaine by marijuana users who have not tried cocaine by this relatively late age and may thus not be representative of unobservables for younger cohorts. Conversely, to the extent that late cocaine initiation reflects a lower propensity for intoxication, this estimate of the gateway effect may instead be conservative. Third, cohort effects may make this esti- mate inapplicable for the comparable age group today. In particular, the demand for illegal drugs has apparently shifted down in the last decade in response to attitudinal changes [SAMHSA, 1996]. Even conditional on the generalizability of the estimate obtained here, policy im- plications depend crucially on the contemporaneous relationship between marijuana and alcohol use. If these drugs are indeed complements, as indicated here and in Saffer and Chaloupka [1996], then policy should clearly aim to restrict youth mari- juana use. On the other hand, if these drugs are in fact substitutes, as several previ- ously cited studies have found, then restrictive marijuana policy involves a tradeoff between reducing future cocaine demand and increasing current alcohol demand.
  • 34. The latter is problematic because alcohol intoxication most likely involves greater health, accident and crime risks than marijuana intoxication. Similarly, policy impli- cations depend on the nature of the unobserved factors found here to be responsible for the inconsistency in the OLS estimates, since they reflect a component of the contemporaneous relationship between marijuana and cocaine. Namely, does the negative correlation between unobservables affecting marijuana and cocaine imply that restrictive marijuana policy would push teenagers and young adults to substi- tute cocaine for marijuana at an earlier age rather than simply block the gateway to cocaine use? To further clarify policy goals, future research should attempt to identify the fun- damental relationships underlying the gateway from marijuana to cocaine. In par- ticular, empirical analysis should seek to establish the relative importance of mari- juana addiction, the contemporaneous relationship between marijuana and cocaine, and the direct intertemporal effect that exists because both drugs produce euphoria. For instance, Pacula [1997] reports evidence of both addictive marijuana and strong contemporaneous complementarity between alcohol and marijuana, but fails to find a This content downloaded from 130.166.3.5 on Tue, 18 Nov 2014 03:18:48 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
  • 35. http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp 162 EASTERN ECONOMIC JOURNAL separate direct gateway from alcohol to marijuana.12 Comparable information for the gateway from marijuana to cocaine can delineate the role that reducing the persis- tence over time of marijuana use must play in the effort to avert the progression from marijuana to cocaine use. NOTES I am grateñil to Frank Chaloupka and Mike Grossman of the National Bureau of Economic Research for graciously providing the cocaine price data used herein, the Bureau of Labor Statistics for allow- ing my use of the restricted NLSY geocode data, and two anonymous referees and the editor for suggestions that substantially improved the paper. 1. Even though Mt_h is a predetermined variable in equation (1), this issue is empirically relevant because many determinants of marijuana and cocaine use are either time-invariant or highly corre- lated over time, as is marijuana consumption if it is indeed addictive. 2. For this reason, though I label equation (2) as a marijuana demand equation and later analyze it as such, it is more strictly interpreted as an instrumenting equation. It should be noted, though, that the use of lagged rather than current values of X does not
  • 36. change the estimates of equation (2) much. 3. In addition, data constraints dictate the use of binary measures of drug consumption, as discussed in the following section. 4. Lack of information on lifetime cocaine use in 1980 prevents the estimation of the relationship be- tween 19S0 marijuana use and 19S4 cocaine use. 5. All monetary variables are converted to 1982-84 equivalents using the CPI for all urban consumers. 6. As explained in detail in Grossman et al. [1996b], a regression of the price of the transaction on its weight and purity and a set of city and year dummies is run and then used to predict a standardized price for each city and year. This procedure is similar to the ones developed by Caulkins [1994] and Saffer and Chaloupka [1996]. These standardized prices were generously supplied to me by Frank Chaloupka and Mike Grossman of NBER. I then created a past year price by taking a weighted average of the 1987 and 1988 prices for each city based on the interview month. Since a price esti- mate exists for at least one city in each state, each county of residence in the NLSY is assigned the price from the city within the same state that is geographically closest. Although the matching pro- cess introduces measurement error that most likely biases the estimates of the price elasticity of marijuana and cocaine demand towards zero, the imputed prices should be reasonably accurate for the large majority of the sample that resides in urban areas. 7. The retail price of marijuana would be the ideal instrumental
  • 37. variable for marijuana use. However, because DEA agents do not focus on apprehending marijuana dealers, the number of marijuana purchases recorded in the DEA database that generate the cocaine price estimates used here is insufficient to estimate a reliable price series for marijuana. 8. The maximum prison term yields almost identical results to the midpoint of the range of the poten- tial prison term, or any other weighted average of the minimum and maximum prison sentence, because the minimum prison term exceeds zero in only two states, Arizona (mandatory 1.5 years) and West Virginia (range from 3 to 6 months). Note that beyond the two included variables, other measures of state-level marijuana penalties, including minimum and maximum fines for possession and an indicator of decriminalization, are not significantly related to marijuana use. 9. The reasons for excluding the remaining 5,407 respondents from the original NLSY cohort are as follows. First, the 1,280 members of the military sample are not included, though in any event 1,079 of these respondents are dropped from the NLSY after 1984 and accordingly the necessary informa- tion for inclusion exists for only 113 people out of the original 1,280. An additional 1,320 respondents are not interviewed in one of the two years. The sample next omits the 397 individuals who are in the military (although drug price and penalty variables could not be matched for this group in any case because states of residence are not recorded for military respondents) and the 190 respondents who are incarcerated at the time of either interview, since these people may not have the same opportu-
  • 38. nity to consume illegal drugs as others. Another 120 individuals live outside the United States in This content downloaded from 130.166.3.5 on Tue, 18 Nov 2014 03:18:48 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp IS MARIJUANA A GATEWAY DRUG? 163 either 19S4 or 1988, while an additional 1,484 respondents have consumed cocaine by the 1984 interview. The remaining exclusions occur because values are missing for one of the two drug use variables in 162 cases and for an explanatory variable in 454 instances. 10. A separate potential source of bias is the refusal of drug users to answer the survey questions on drug use. Refusal bias seems improbable, though, because missing values for either 19S4 marijuana or 19SS cocaine use are responsible for the exclusion of only 162 individuals. Moreover, although 156 of these respondents report marijuana use but not cocaine use, the prevalence of marijuana use among these respondents, 17.9 percent, is slightly lower than the prevalence of 24.6 percent among sample respondents. 11. To maintain unbiasedness under this scenario, underreporters must be less likely to use marijuana than others, rather than equally likely as in the case in which cocaine use is underreported only in 1988.
  • 39. 12. Though in her analysis marijuana plays the role of cocaine here, Pacula [1997] does not eliminate previous users of marijuana from her sample and therefore must consider marijuana addiction as an additional element of the intertemporal relationship between alcohol and marijuana. REFERENCES Becker, G. and Murphy, K. A Theory of Rational Addiction. Journal of Political Economy, August 1988, 675-700. Beer Institute. Brewer's Almanac. Washington, D.C.: U.S. Brewer's Association, 1995. Blundell, R. and Smith, R. Estimation in a Class of Simultaneous Equation Limited Dependent Vari- able Models. Review of Economic Studies, January 1989, 37-57. Bound, J., Jaegar, D., and Baker, R. Problems With Instrumental Variables Estimation When the Correlation Between the Instruments and the Endogenous Explanatory Variable is Weak. Jour- nal of the American Statistical Association, June 1995, 443-50. Cadoret, R. Genetic and Environmental Factors in Initiation of Drug Abuse and the Transition to Abuse, in Vulnerability to Drug Abuse, edited by M. Glantz and R. Pickens. Washington, D.C.: American Psychological Association, 1992. Caulkins, J. Developing Price Series for Cocaine. Santa Monica, CA: RAND, 1994. Center for Human Resource Research. NLS User's Guide.
  • 40. Columbus, OH: Ohio State University, 1995. Chaloupka, F. Rational Addictive Behavior and Cigarette Smokmg. Journal of Political Economy, Au- gust 1991, 722-742. Chaloupka, F. and Laixuthai, A. Do Youths Substitute Alcohol and Marijuana.'' borne üiconometnc Evidence. NBER Working Paper No. 4662, February 1994. DeSimone, J. Illegal Drug Use and Labor Supply. Unpublished manuscript, Yale University, November 1997. DiNardo, J. and Lemieux, T. Alcohol, Marijuana, and American Youth: The Unintended Effects of Government Regulation. NBER Working Paper No. 4212, November 1992. Grossman, M., Chaloupka, F., and Brown, C. The Demand for Marijuana by Young Adults: A Katio- nal Addiction Approach. Unpublished manuscript, National Bureau of Economic Research, April 1996a. . The Demand for Cocaine by Young Adults: A Rational Addiction Approach. NBER Working Paper No. 5713, August 1996b. Gujarati, D. Basic Econometrics. New York: McGraw-Hill, 1995. Hausman, J. Specification Tests in Econometrics. Econometrica, November 1978, 1251-71. Hoyt, G. and Chaloupka, F. Effect of Survey Conditions on
  • 41. Selt-Keported Substance use. contempo- rary Economic Policy, July 1994, 109-21. Johnston, L., O'Malley, P. and Bachman, J. Illicit Drug Use, Smoking ana Drinking ay Americas High School Students, College Students, and Young Adults. Washington, D.C.: U.S. Department of Health and Human Services, 1988. Kandel, D. and Yamaguchi, K. From Beer to Crack: Developmental Patterns of Drug Involvement. American Journal of Public Health, June 1993, 851-55. This content downloaded from 130.166.3.5 on Tue, 18 Nov 2014 03:18:48 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp 164 EASTERN ECONOMIC JOURNAL Kenkel, D. and Ribar, D. Alcohol Consumption and Young Adults* Socioeconomic Status. Brookings Papers on Economic Activity: Microeconomics, 1994, 119-61. Kleiman, M. Against Excess: Drug Policy for Results. New York: Basic Books, 1992. Lee, L. Amemiya's Generalized Least Squares and Tests of Overidentification in Simultaneous Equation Models with Qualitative or Limited Dependent Variables. Center for Economic Research Discus- sion Paper No. 262, University of Minnesota, May 1991.
  • 42. Mensch, B. and Kandel, D. Underreporting of Substance Use in a National Longitudinal Youth Cohort. Public Opinion Quarterly, Spring 1988, 100-24. Merikangas, K., Rounsaville, B., and Prusoff, B. Familial Factors in Vulnerability to Substance Abuse, in Vulnerability to Drug Abuse, edited by M. Glantz and R. Pickens. Washington, D.C.: American Psvcholocical Association. 1992. Mills, C. and Noyes, H. Patterns and Correlates of Initial and Subsequent Drug Use Among Adoles- cents. Journal of Consulting and Clinical Psychology, April 1984, 231-43. Model, K. The Effect of Marijuana Decriminalization on Hospital Emergency Room Drug Episodes: 1975- 1978. Journal of the American Statistical Association, September 1993, 737-47. Newcomb, M. and Bentler, P. Cocaine Use Among Adolescents: Longitudinal Associations with Social Context, Psychopathology, and Use of Other Substances. Addictive Behaviors, November 1986, 263-73. O'Donnell, J. and Clayton, R. The Stepping-Stone Hypothesis - Marijuana, Heroin and Causality. Chemical Dependencies, March 1982, 229-41. Pacula, R. Adolescent Alcohol and Marijuana Consumption: Is There Really a Gateway Effect? Unpub- lished manuscript, University of San Diego, 1997. Saffer, H. and Chaloupka, F. The Demand for Illicit Drugs. Unpublished manuscript, National Bureau
  • 43. of Economic Research, 1996. Sickles, R. and Taubman, P. Who Uses Illegal Drugs? American Economic Review, May 1991, 248-51. Smith, R. and Blundell, R. An Exogeneity Test for a Simultaneous Equation Tobit Model with an Application to Labor Supply. Econometrica, May 1986, 679-85. Stigler, G. and Becker, G. De Gustibus Non Est Disputandum. American Economic Review, March 1977, 76-90. Substance Abuse and Mental Health Services Administration (SAMHSA). National Household Survey on Drug Abuse: Population Estimates 1995. Rockville, MD: U.S. Department of Health and Human Services, 1996. Yamaguchi, K. and Kandel, D. Patterns of Drug Use from Adolescence to Young Adulthood: 111. Predic- tors of Progression. American Journal of Public Health, July 1984, 673-81. This content downloaded from 130.166.3.5 on Tue, 18 Nov 2014 03:18:48 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jspArticle Contentsp. 149p. 150p. 151p. 152p. 153p. 154p. 155p. 156p. 157p. 158p. 159p. 160p. 161p. 162p. 163p. 164Issue Table of ContentsEastern Economic Journal, Vol. 24, No. 2 (Spring, 1998), pp. 127-251Front MatterMonetary Rules [pp. 127- 136]New Deal Agricultural Appropriations: A Political Influence [pp. 137-148]Is Marijuana a Gateway Drug? [pp. 149- 164]Does the Minimum Wage Affect Employment in Mexico?
  • 44. [pp. 165-180]Coping Rationally with Unpreferred Preferences [pp. 181-194]Does the Federal Reserve Lexicographically Order Its Policy Objectives? [pp. 195-206]Revisiting Long-Run Industry Supply [pp. 207-215]Islamic and Neo-Confucian Perspectives on the New Traditional Economy [pp. 217- 227]Other Things EqualSmall Worlds, or, the Preposterousness of Closed Economy Macro [pp. 229-232]Book ReviewsReview: untitled [pp. 233-235]Review: untitled [pp. 235-238]Review: untitled [pp. 238-240]Review: untitled [pp. 240-242]Review: untitled [pp. 242-244]Review: untitled [pp. 244-247]Review: untitled [pp. 247-249]Review: untitled [pp. 250-251]Back Matter The University of Chicago The Booth School of Business of the University of Chicago The University of Chicago Law School Medical Marijuana Laws, Traffic Fatalities, and Alcohol Consumption Author(s): D. Mark Anderson, Benjamin Hansen, and Daniel I. Rees Source: Journal of Law and Economics, Vol. 56, No. 2 (May 2013), pp. 333-369 Published by: The University of Chicago Press for The Booth School of Business of the University of Chicago and The University of Chicago Law School Stable URL: http://www.jstor.org/stable/10.1086/668812 . Accessed: 18/11/2014 03:00 Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available at . http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp .
  • 45. JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide range of content in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and facilitate new forms of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact [email protected] . The University of Chicago Press, The University of Chicago, The Booth School of Business of the University of Chicago, The University of Chicago Law School are collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend access to Journal of Law and Economics. http://www.jstor.org This content downloaded from 130.166.3.5 on Tue, 18 Nov 2014 03:00:05 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions http://www.jstor.org/action/showPublisher?publisherCode=ucpr ess http://www.jstor.org/action/showPublisher?publisherCode=chica gobooth http://www.jstor.org/action/showPublisher?publisherCode=chica gobooth http://www.jstor.org/action/showPublisher?publisherCode=chica golaw http://www.jstor.org/stable/10.1086/668812?origin=JSTOR-pdf http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp 333
  • 46. [Journal of Law and Economics, vol. 56 (May 2013)] � 2013 by The University of Chicago. All rights reserved. 0022-2186/2013/5602-0011$10.00 Medical Marijuana Laws, Traffic Fatalities, and Alcohol Consumption D. Mark Anderson Montana State University Benjamin Hansen University of Oregon Daniel I. Rees University of Colorado Denver Abstract To date, 19 states have passed medical marijuana laws, yet very little is known about their effects. The current study examines the relationship between the legalization of medical marijuana and traffic fatalities, the leading cause of death among Americans ages 5–34. The first full year after coming into effect, legal- ization is associated with an 8–11 percent decrease in traffic fatalities. The impact of legalization on traffic fatalities involving alcohol is larger and estimated with more precision than its impact on traffic fatalities that do not involve alcohol. Legalization is also associated with sharp decreases in the price of marijuana and alcohol consumption, which suggests that marijuana and alcohol are sub- stitutes. Because alternative mechanisms cannot be ruled out, the negative re-
  • 47. lationship between legalization and alcohol-related traffic fatalities does not necessarily imply that driving under the influence of marijuana is safer than driving under the influence of alcohol. 1. Introduction Medical marijuana laws (MMLs) remove state-level penalties for using, pos- sessing, and cultivating medical marijuana. Patients are required to obtain ap- proval or certification from a doctor, and doctors who recommend marijuana to their patients are immune from prosecution. Medical marijuana laws allow patients to designate caregivers who can obtain marijuana on their behalf. We would like to thank Dean Anderson, Brian Cadena, Christopher Carpenter, Chad Cotti, Ben- jamin Crost, Scott Cunningham, Brian Duncan, Andrew Friedson, Darren Grant, Mike Hanlon, Rosalie Pacula, Henri Pellerin, Claus Pörtner, Randy Rucker, Doug Young, and seminar participants at Clemson University, Colorado State University, Cornell University, and the National Bureau of Economics and Research Health Economics Program Meeting in April 2012 for comments and suggestions. This content downloaded from 130.166.3.5 on Tue, 18 Nov 2014 03:00:05 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp
  • 48. 334 The Journal of LAW & ECONOMICS On May 2, 2013, Maryland became the nineteenth state, along with the District of Columbia, to enact an MML. More than a dozen state legislatures, including those of Illinois, New York, and Pennsylvania, have recently considered medical marijuana bills. If these bills are eventually signed into law, the majority of Americans will live in states that permit the use of medical marijuana. Opponents of medical marijuana tend to focus on the social issues surrounding substance use. They argue that marijuana is addictive, serves as a gateway drug, has little medicinal value, and leads to criminal activity (Adams 2008; Blankstein 2010). Proponents argue that marijuana is both efficacious and safe and can be used to treat the side effects of chemotherapy as well as the symptoms of AIDS, multiple sclerosis, epilepsy, glaucoma, and other serious illnesses. They cite clin- ical research showing that marijuana relieves chronic pain, nausea, muscle spasms, and appetite loss (Eddy 2010; Marmor 1998; Watson, Benson, and Joy 2000) and note that neither the link between the use of medical marijuana and the use of other substances nor the link between medical marijuana and criminal activity has been substantiated (Belville 2011; Corry et al.
  • 49. 2009; Hoeffel 2011). This study begins by using price data collected from back issues of High Times, the leading cannabis-related magazine in the United States, to explore the effects of MMLs on the market for marijuana. Our results are consistent with anecdotal evidence that MMLs have led to a substantial increase in the supply of high- grade marijuana (Montgomery 2010). In contrast, the impact of MMLs on the market for low-quality marijuana appears to be modest. Next, we turn our attention to MMLs and traffic fatalities, the primary re- lationship of interest. Traffic fatalities are the leading cause of death among Americans ages 5–34.1 To our knowledge, there has been no previous examination of this relationship. Data on traffic fatalities at the state level are obtained from the Fatality Analysis Reporting System (FARS) for the years 1990–2010. Fourteen states and the District of Columbia enacted an MML during this period. The FARS information includes the time of day the traffic fatality occurred, the day of the week it occurred, and whether alcohol was involved. Using this infor- mation, we contribute to the long-standing debate on whether marijuana and alcohol are substitutes or complements. The first full year after coming into effect, the legalization of medical marijuana
  • 50. is associated with an 8–11 percent decrease in traffic fatalities. However, the effect of MMLs on traffic fatalities involving alcohol is larger and estimated with more precision than the effect of MMLs on traffic fatalities that do not involve alcohol. In addition, we find that the estimated effects of MMLs on fatalities at night and on weekends (when the level of alcohol consumption increases) are larger, and are more precise, than the estimated effects of MMLs on fatalities during the day and on weekdays. 1 These 2010 data on leading causes of fatalities are from the Centers for Disease Control and Prevention’s Web-Based Injury Statistics Query and Reporting System (http://www.cdc.gov/injury/ wisqars). This content downloaded from 130.166.3.5 on Tue, 18 Nov 2014 03:00:05 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions http://www.cdc.gov/injury/wisqars http://www.cdc.gov/injury/wisqars http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp Medical Marijuana Laws 335 Finally, the relationship between MMLs and more direct measures of alcohol consumption is examined. Using individual-level data from the Behavioral Risk Factor Surveillance System (BRFSS) for the period 1993–2010,
  • 51. we find that MMLs are associated with decreases in the probability of having consumed alcohol in the past month, binge drinking, and the number of drinks consumed. We conclude that alcohol is the likely mechanism through which the legali- zation of medical marijuana reduces traffic fatalities. However, this conclusion does not necessarily imply that driving under the influence of marijuana is safer than driving under the influence of alcohol. Alcohol is often consumed in res- taurants and bars, while many states prohibit the use of medical marijuana in public. If marijuana consumption typically takes place at home or other private locations, then legalization could reduce traffic fatalities simply because mari- juana users are less likely to drive while impaired. 2. Background 2.1. A Brief History of Medical Marijuana Marijuana was introduced in the United States in the early 1600s by Jamestown settlers who used the plant in hemp production; hemp cultivation remained a prominent industry until the mid-1800s (Deitch 2003). During the census of 1850, the United States recorded more than 8,000 cannabis plantations of at least 2,000 acres (Cannabis Campaigners Guide 2011). Throughout this period,
  • 52. marijuana was commonly used by physicians and pharmacists to treat a broad spectrum of ailments (Pacula et al. 2002). From 1850 to 1942, marijuana was included in the United States Pharmacopoeia, the official list of recognized me- dicinal drugs (Bilz 1992). In 1913, California passed the first marijuana prohibition law aimed at rec- reational use (Gieringer 1999); by 1936, the remaining 47 states had followed suit (Eddy 2010). In 1937, the Marihuana Tax Act (Pub. L. No. 75-238, ch. 553, 50 Stat. 551 [1937]) effectively discontinued the use of marijuana for medicinal purposes (Bilz 1992), and marijuana was classified as a Schedule I drug in 1970.2 According to the Controlled Substances Act, a Schedule I drug must have a “high potential for abuse” and “no currently accepted medical use in treatment in the United States” (Eddy 2010, p. 3). In 1996, California passed the Compassionate Use Act, which removed crim- inal penalties for using, possessing, and cultivating medical marijuana. It also provided immunity from prosecution to physicians who recommended the use of medical marijuana to their patients. Before 1996, a number of states allowed doctors to prescribe marijuana, but this had little practical effect because of
  • 53. 2 The Marihuana Tax Act imposed a registration tax and required extensive record keeping and thus increased the cost of prescribing marijuana as compared to other drugs (Bilz 1992). This content downloaded from 130.166.3.5 on Tue, 18 Nov 2014 03:00:05 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp 336 The Journal of LAW & ECONOMICS Table 1 Medical Marijuana Laws, 1990–2010 State Effective Date Alaska March 4, 1999 California November 6, 1996 Colorado June 1, 2001 District of Columbia July 27, 2010 Hawaii December 28, 2000 Maine December 22, 1999 Michigan December 4, 2008 Montana November 2, 2004 Nevada October 1, 2001 New Jersey October 1, 2010 New Mexico July 1, 2007 Oregon December 3, 1998 Rhode Island January 3, 2006 Vermont July 1, 2004 Washington November 3, 1998
  • 54. Note. Arizona, Connecticut, Delaware, Maryland, and Massachusetts legalized medical marijuana after 2010. federal restrictions.3 Since 1996, 18 other states and the District of Columbia have joined California in legalizing the use of medical marijuana (Table 1), although it is still classified as a Schedule I drug by the federal government.4 2.2. Studies on Substance Use and Driving Laboratory studies have shown that cannabis use impairs driving-related func- tions such as distance perception, reaction time, and hand-eye coordination (Kelly, Darke, and Ross 2004; Sewell, Poling, and Sofuoglu 2009). However, neither simulator nor driving-course studies provide consistent evidence that these impairments to driving-related functions lead to an increased risk of col- lision (Kelly, Darke, and Ross 2004; Sewell, Poling, and Sofuoglu 2009), perhaps because drivers under the influence of tetrahydrocannabinol (THC), the primary psychoactive substance in marijuana, engage in compensatory behaviors such as reducing their velocity, avoiding risky maneuvers, and increasing their following distances (Kelly, Darke, and Ross 2004; Sewell, Poling, and Sofuoglu 2009). Like marijuana, alcohol impairs driving-related functions such as reaction time and hand-eye coordination (Kelly, Darke, and Ross 2004;
  • 55. Sewell, Poling, and Sofuoglu 2009). Moreover, simulator and driving-course studies provide une- 3 Federal regulations prohibit doctors from writing prescriptions for marijuana. In addition, even if a doctor were to illegally prescribe marijuana, it would be against federal law for pharmacies to distribute it. Doctors in states that have legalized medical marijuana avoid violating federal law by recommending marijuana to their patients rather than prescribing its use. 4 Information on when medical marijuana laws (MMLs) were passed was obtained from a Con- gressional Research Services Report by Eddy (2010). Although the New Jersey medical marijuana law went into effect on October 1, 2010, implementation has been delayed (Brittain 2012). Coding New Jersey as a state without medical marijuana in 2010 has no appreciable impact on our results. This content downloaded from 130.166.3.5 on Tue, 18 Nov 2014 03:00:05 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp Medical Marijuana Laws 337 quivocal evidence that alcohol consumption leads to an increased risk of collision (Kelly, Darke, and Ross 2004; Sewell, Poling, and Sofuoglu 2009). Even at low doses, drivers under the influence of alcohol tend to
  • 56. underestimate the degree to which they are impaired (MacDonald et al. 2008; Marczinski, Harrison, and Fillmore 2008; Robbe and O’Hanlon 1993; Sewell, Poling, and Sofuoglu 2009), drive at faster speeds, and take more risks (Burian, Liguori, and Robinson 2002; Ronen et al. 2008; Sewell, Poling, and Sofuoglu 2009). When used in conjunction with marijuana, alcohol appears to have an “additive or even multiplicative” effect on driving-related functions (Sewell, Poling, and Sofuoglu 2009, p. 186), although chronic marijuana users may be less impaired by alcohol than infre- quent users (Jones and Stone 1970; Marks and MacAvoy 1989; Wright and Terry 2002).5 2.3. The Relationship between Marijuana and Alcohol Although THC has not been linked to an increased risk of collision in simulator and driving-course studies, MMLs could impact traffic fatalities through the consumption of alcohol. While a number of studies have found evidence of complementarity between marijuana and alcohol (Pacula 1998; Farrelly et al. 1999; Williams et al. 2004), others lend support to the hypothesis that marijuana and alcohol are substitutes. For instance, Chaloupka and Laixuthai (1997) and Saffer and Chaloupka (1999) found that marijuana decriminalization led to decreased alcohol consumption, while DiNardo and Lemieux
  • 57. (2001) found that increases in the minimum legal drinking age were positively associated with the use of marijuana. Two recent studies used a regression discontinuity approach to examine the effect of the minimum legal drinking age on marijuana use but came to different conclusions. Crost and Guerrero (2012) analyzed data from the National Survey on Drug Use and Health (NSDUH). They found that marijuana use decreased sharply at 21 years of age, evidence consistent with substitutability between alcohol and marijuana. In contrast, Yörük and Yörük (2011), who drew on data from the National Longitudinal Survey of Youth 1997 (NLSY97), concluded that alcohol and marijuana were complements. However, these authors appear to have inadvertently conditioned on having used marijuana at least once since the last interview. When Crost and Rees (2013) applied Yörük and Yörük’s (2011) research design to the NLSY97 data without conditioning on having used mar- ijuana since the last interview, they found no evidence that alcohol and marijuana were complements. 5 A large body of research in epidemiology attempts to assess the effects of substance use on the basis of observed tetrahydrocannabinol and alcohol levels in the blood of drivers who have been in accidents. For marijuana, the results have been mixed, while the
  • 58. likelihood of an accident occurring clearly increases with blood alcohol concentration (BAC) levels (Sewell, Poling, and Sofuoglu 2009). This content downloaded from 130.166.3.5 on Tue, 18 Nov 2014 03:00:05 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp 338 The Journal of LAW & ECONOMICS 3. Medical Marijuana Laws and the Marijuana Market Medical marijuana laws should, in theory, increase both the supply of mar- ijuana and the demand for marijuana, unambiguously leading to an increase in consumption (Pacula et al. 2010). They afford suppliers some protection against prosecution and allow patients to buy medical marijuana without fear of being arrested or fined, which lowers the full cost of obtaining marijuana.6 Because it is prohibitively expensive for the government to ensure that all medicinal mar- ijuana ends up in the hands of registered patients (especially in states that permit home cultivation), diversion to nonpatients almost certainly occurs.7 The NSDUH is the best source of information on marijuana consumption by adults living in the United States. However, the NSDUH does not provide
  • 59. individual-level data with state identifiers to researchers and did not publish state-level estimates of marijuana use prior to 1999.8 Because five states (including California, Oregon, and Washington) legalized medical marijuana during the period 1996–99, we turn to back issues of High Times magazine in order to gauge the impact of legalization on the marijuana market. Begun in 1975, High Times is published monthly and covers topics ranging from marijuana cultivation to politics. Each issue also contains a section entitled “Trans High Market Quo- tations” in which readers provide marijuana prices from across the country. In addition to price, a typical entry includes information about where the marijuana was purchased, its strain, and its quality. We collected price information from High Times for the period 1990–2011. Jacobson (2004), who collected information on the price of marijuana from High 6 The majority of MMLs allow patients to register on the basis of medical conditions that cannot be objectively confirmed (for example, chronic pain and nausea). In fact, chronic pain is the most common medical condition among patients seeking treatment (see Table A1). According to recent Arizona registry data, only seven of 11,186 applications for medical marijuana have been denied approval. Sun (2010) described “quick-in, quick-out mills,” where physicians provide recommen- dations for a nominal fee. Cochran (2010) reported on doctors
  • 60. providing medical marijuana rec- ommendations to patients via brief Web interviews on Skype. 7 Aside from Washington, D.C., and New Jersey, all MMLs enacted during the period 1990–2010 allowed for home cultivation, and eight of 15 allowed patients or caregivers to cultivate collectively (see Table A2). A recent investigation concluded that thousands of pounds of medical marijuana grown in Colorado are diverted annually to the recreational market (Wirfs-Brock, Seaton, and Sutherland 2010). Thurstone, Lieberman, and Schmiege (2011) interviewed 80 adolescents (15–19 years of age) undergoing outpatient substance abuse treatment in Denver. Thirty-nine of the 80 reported having obtained marijuana from someone with a medical marijuana license. Florio (2011) described the story of four eighth graders in Montana who received marijuana-laced cookies from a registered medical marijuana patient. 8 Using these estimates, Wall et al. (2011, p. 714) found that rates of marijuana use among 12– 17-year-olds were higher in states that had legalized medical marijuana than in states that had not, but they noted that “in the years prior to MML passage, there was already a higher prevalence of use and lower perceptions of risk” in states that had legalized medical marijuana. Using NSDUH data for the years 2002–9, Harper, Strumpf, and Kaufman (2012) found that legalization was associated with a small reduction in the rate of marijuana use among 12– 17-year-olds. Using data for the period 1995–2002 from Denver, Los Angeles, Portland, San Diego, and San Jose, Gorman and Huber (2007) found little evidence that marijuana consumption increased
  • 61. among adult arrestees as a result of legalization. This content downloaded from 130.166.3.5 on Tue, 18 Nov 2014 03:00:05 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp Medical Marijuana Laws 339 Table 2 Medical Marijuana Laws and the Price of High-Quality Marijuana, 1990–2011 (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) MML �.304** (.037) �.103� (.058) 3 Years before MML .022 (.074) 2 Years before MML .003 (.075) 1 Year before MML �.037 (.076) Year of law change �.117�
  • 62. (.061) �.059 (.069) �.060 (.096) 1 Year after MML �.156** (.044) �.082 (.070) �.084 (.097) 2 Years after MML �.203** (.074) �.110 (.082) �.113 (.120) 3 Years after MML �.211** (.062) �.128 (.084) �.130 (.118) 4 Years after MML �.387**
  • 63. (.123) �.283* (.115) �.286* (.125) 5� Years after MML �.439** (.048) �.257* (.116) �.262� (.145) R2 .224 .310 .241 .315 .315 State-specific linear time trends No Yes No Yes Yes Note. The dependent variable is equal to the natural log of the median price of marijuana in state s and year t. Standard errors, corrected for clustering at the state level, are in parentheses. Year fixed effects, state fixed effects, and state covariates are included in all specifications. MML p medical marijuana law. N p 920. � Statistically significant at the 10% level. * Statistically significant at the 5% level. ** Statistically significant at the 1% level. Times for the period 1975–2000, distinguished between high- quality (a category that included Californian and Hawaiian sinsemilla) and low- quality (a category that included commercial grade Colombian and Mexican weed)
  • 64. marijuana.9 Following Jacobson (2004), we classified marijuana purchases by quality and calculated the median per-ounce price by state and year.10 Table 2 presents 9 The plant variety (that is, strain), which part of the plant is used, the method of storage, and cultivation techniques are all important determinants of quality and potency (McLaren et al. 2008). In recent decades, there has been a marked trend toward indoor cultivation and higher potency in the United States (McLaren et al. 2008). Jacobson (2004) argued that, ideally, prices would be deflated by a measure of potency. Unfortunately, information on potency is not available in the High Times data. 10 A total of 8,271 purchases were coded. Of these, 7,029 were classified as high quality and 1,242 were classified as low quality. Prior to 2004, information on the seller was occasionally included in the “Trans High Market Quotations” section of High Times. Although dispensaries were never men- tioned, they are a relatively recent phenomenon. The number of dispensaries in California expanded rapidly after 2004 (Jacobson et al. 2011), and the number of dispensaries in Colorado and Montana expanded rapidly after 2008 (Smith 2011, 2012). We compared High Times price data for 2011–12 with price data posted on the Internet by 84 dispensaries located in seven states. In four states (California, Michigan, Nevada, and Washington), the prices charged by dispensaries were statistically
  • 65. This content downloaded from 130.166.3.5 on Tue, 18 Nov 2014 03:00:05 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp 340 The Journal of LAW & ECONOMICS estimates of the following equation: ln(Price of high-quality marijuana ) p b � b MML � X bst 0 1 st st 2 (1) � v � w � � ,s t st where s indexes states and t indexes years. The variable MMLst indicates whether medical marijuana was legal in state s and year t, and b1 represents the estimated relationship between legalization and the per ounce price of high-quality mar- ijuana. The vector Xst includes controls for the mean age in state s and year t, the unemployment rate, per capita income, whether the state had a marijuana decriminalization law in place, and the beer tax. State fixed effects, represented by vs, control for time-invariant unobservable factors at the state level; year fixed effects, represented by wt, control for common shocks to the price of high-quality marijuana.11 The baseline estimate suggests that the supply response to legalization is larger
  • 66. than the demand response. In particular, legalization is associated with a 26.2 percent ( ) decrease in the price of high-quality marijuana.�.304e � 1 p �.262 When we include state-specific linear time trends, intended to control for omitted variables at the state level that evolve at a constant rate, legalization is associated with a 9.8 percent decrease in the price of high-quality marijuana. Lagging the MML indicator provides evidence that the effect of legalization on the price of high-quality marijuana is not immediate. Controlling for state- specific linear time trends, we see that the estimated coefficients of the MML indicator lagged 1–3 years are negative but not statistically significant. There is indistinguishable from the prices provided by High Times readers. In Arizona, Colorado, and Oregon, the prices charged by dispensaries were significantly lower than the prices provided by High Times readers; however, these differences were generally not large in magnitude. The greatest difference was in Colorado, where dispensaries, on average, charged 24.4 percent less per ounce ($72.80) than the prices provided by High Times readers. In Arizona, dispensaries, on average, charged 10.3 percent less per ounce ($36.60) than the prices provided by High Times readers; in Oregon, dispensaries, on average, charged 14.9 percent less per ounce ($37.20) than the prices provided by High Times readers (for dispensary price data, see WeedMaps.com, Dispensaries [http://www.legalmarijuanadispensary
  • 67. .com]). 11 Standard errors are corrected for clustering at the state level (Bertrand, Duflo, and Mullainathan 2004). Descriptive statistics are presented in Table A3. The mean age in state s and year t was calculated using census data. The data on beer taxes are from Brewers Almanac (Beer Institute 1990– 2010). The unemployment and income data are from the Bureau of Labor Statistics and the Bureau of Economic Analysis, respectively. The data on decriminalization laws are from Model (1993) and Scott (2010). During the period under study, the decriminalization indicator captures only two policy changes: Nevada and Massachusetts decriminalized the use of marijuana in 2001 and 2010, respec- tively. The majority of decriminalization laws were passed prior to 1990. Following Jacobson’s ap- proach (2004), the estimates presented in Tables 2 and 3 are unweighted. When the regressions are weighted by the number of observations used to calculate the median price and state-specific linear time trends are included on the right-hand side, estimates of the relationship between legalization and price are smaller and less precise than those reported in Tables 2 and 3. Nevertheless, they continue to show that legalization is associated with a statistically significant reduction in the price of high-quality marijuana after 4 years. When the regressions are weighted by the number of ob- servations used to calculate the median price but state-specific linear time trends are not included on the right-hand side, estimates of the relationship between legalization and price are similar to those reported in Tables 2 and 3.
  • 68. This content downloaded from 130.166.3.5 on Tue, 18 Nov 2014 03:00:05 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions http://www.legalmarijuanadispensary.com http://www.legalmarijuanadispensary.com http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp Medical Marijuana Laws 341 Table 3 Medical Marijuana Laws and the Price of Low-Quality Marijuana, 1990–2011 (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) MML �.096 (.105) �.075 (.150) 3 Years before MML .135 (.197) 2 Years before MML .103 (.108) 1 Year before MML �.088 (.200) Year of law change �.035 (.154)
  • 69. �.056 (.193) �.013 (.196) 1 Year after MML �.250� (.146) �.182 (.176) �.106 (.136) 2 Years after MML �.058 (.176) �.016 (.190) .053 (.166) 3 Years after MML �.244* (.098) �.114 (.141) �.028 (.138) 4 Years after MML .032 (.403)
  • 70. .046 (.373) .131 (.429) 5� Years after MML �.038 (.073) .271 (.335) .370 (.267) R2 .720 .748 .723 .751 .753 State-specific linear time trends No Yes No Yes Yes Note. The dependent variable is equal to the natural log of the median price of marijuana in state s and year t. Standard errors, corrected for clustering at the state level, are in parentheses. Year fixed effects, state fixed effects, and state covariates are included in all specifications. MML p medical marijuana law. N p 483. � Statistically significant at the 10% level. * Statistically significant at the 5% level. a statistically significant 24.6 percent reduction in the price of high-quality mar- ijuana in the fourth full year after legalization. This pattern of results is consistent with state registry data from Colorado, Montana, and Rhode Island showing that patient numbers increased slowly in the years immediately
  • 71. after legalization.12 Adding leads to the model with state-specific linear time trends produces no evidence that legalization was systematically preceded by changes in tastes or policies related to the market for high-quality marijuana. Estimates of the relationship between legalization and the price of low-quality marijuana are presented in Table 3. The majority of these estimates are negative. However, with two exceptions, they are statistically insignificant. Given that much of the medicinal crop is grown indoors under ultraviolet lights and that high- 12 Table A1 presents registry information by state. Montana legalized medical marijuana in No- vember 2004. Two years later, only 287 patients were registered; 7 years later, 30,036 patients were registered. The number of registered patients in Colorado increased from 5,051 in January 2009 to 128,698 in June 2011. Patient numbers also appear to be growing rapidly in Arizona, which passed the Arizona Medical Marijuana Act on November 2, 2010. A total of 11,133 patient applications had been approved as of August 29, 2011; 40,463 patient applications had been approved by June 30, 2012. This content downloaded from 130.166.3.5 on Tue, 18 Nov 2014 03:00:05 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp
  • 72. 342 The Journal of LAW & ECONOMICS potency and high-quality strains such as Northern Lights and Super Silver Haze are favored by medical marijuana cultivators, this imprecision is not surprising. 4. Medical Marijuana Laws and Traffic Fatalities The estimates discussed above suggest that legalization leads to a substantial decrease in the price of high-quality marijuana and, presumably, a correspond- ingly large increase in consumption.13 In this section, we test whether the impact of legalization extends to traffic fatalities. 4.1. Data on Traffic Fatalities We use data from FARS for the period 1990–2010 to examine the relationship between MMLs and traffic fatalities. These data are collected by the National Highway Traffic Safety Administration and represent an annual census of all fatal injuries suffered in motor vehicle accidents in the United States. Information on the circumstances of each crash and the persons and vehicles involved is obtained from a variety of sources, including police crash reports, driver licensing files, vehicle registration files, state highway department data, emergency medical services records, medical examiners’ reports, toxicology
  • 73. reports, and death certifi- cates. Table 4 presents descriptive statistics and definitions for our outcome mea- sures. The variable Fatalities Totalst is equal to the number of traffic fatalities per 100,000 people of state s in year t.14 The variables Fatalities (BAC 1 0)st and Fatalities (BAC ≥ .10)st allow us to examine the effects of legalization by alcohol involvement. The variable Fatalities (BAC 1 0)st is equal to the number of traffic fatalities per 100,000 people resulting from accidents in which at least one driver had a positive blood alcohol concentration (BAC). The variable Fatalities (BAC ≥ .10)st is defined analogously, but at least one driver had to have a BAC greater than or equal to .10. The variable Fatalities (No Alcohol)st is equal to the number of fatalities per 100,000 people in which alcohol involvement was not reported.15 13 If we assume, conservatively, that legalization has a negligible impact on demand, then the change in marijuana consumption is equal to the elasticity of demand multiplied by the percentage change in price. Only a handful of researchers have estimated the price elasticity of demand for marijuana. Using data on University of California, Los Angeles, undergraduates, Nisbet and Vakil (1972) estimated a price elasticity of demand between �1.01 and �1.51; using data from Monitoring the Future on high school seniors, Pacula et al. (2001) estimated
  • 74. a 30-day participation elasticity between �.002 and �.69; using data from the Harvard College Alcohol Study, Williams et al. (2004) estimated a 30-day participation elasticity of �.24. 14 For population data, see National Cancer Institute, US Population Data—1969–2011 (http:// seer.cancer.gov/popdata/index.html). According to Eisenberg (2003), traffic fatalities in the Fatality Analysis Reporting System (FARS) are measured with little to no error. We experimented with scaling traffic fatalities by the population of licensed drivers and by the number of miles driven in state s and year t rather than by the state population. These estimates, which are similar in terms of magnitude and precision to those presented here, are available on request. 15 The numerator for Fatalities (No Alcohol)st was determined from two sources in FARS. First, either all drivers involved had to have registered a BAC of zero or, if BAC information was missing, the police had to report that alcohol was not involved. This content downloaded from 130.166.3.5 on Tue, 18 Nov 2014 03:00:05 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions http://seer.cancer.gov/popdata/index.html http://seer.cancer.gov/popdata/index.html http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp Medical Marijuana Laws 343 Table 4
  • 75. Dependent Variables for the Fatality Analysis Reporting System Analysis Dependent Variable Mean Description Fatalities Total 14.58 (5.05) Fatalities per 100,000 people Fatalities (No Alcohol) 9.67 (3.45) Fatalities per 100,000 people with no indication of alcohol involvement Fatalities (BAC 1 0) 3.97 (1.74) Fatalities per 100,000 people for which at least one driver involved had a blood alcohol concentration (BAC) 1 .00 Fatalities (BAC ≥ .10) 3.13 (1.43) Fatalities per 100,000 people for which at least one driver involved had a BAC 1 .10 Fatalities, 15–19 24.55 (9.75) Fatalities per 100,000 people 15– 19 years of age Fatalities, 20–29 23.59 (8.41) Fatalities per 100,000 people 20– 29 years of age Fatalities, 30–39 15.45 (6.49) Fatalities per 100,000 people 30– 39 years of age Fatalities, 40–49 14.00 (5.63) Fatalities per 100,000 people 40– 49 years of age Fatalities, 50–59 13.22 (4.93) Fatalities per 100,000 people 50– 59 years of age Fatalities, 60� 17.39 (5.28) Fatalities per 100,000 people 60 years old and above Fatalities Males 20.48 (7.15) Fatalities per 100,000 males Fatalities Females 9.03 (3.29) Fatalities per 100,000 females Fatalities Weekdays 8.32 (2.88) Fatalities per 100,000 people on weekdays
  • 76. Fatalities Weekends 6.22 (2.25) Fatalities per 100,000 people on weekends Fatalities Daytime 7.04 (2.59) Fatalities per 100,000 people during the day Fatalities Nighttime 7.42 (2.60) Fatalities per 100,000 people during the night Note. The data are weighted means based on the Fatality Analysis Reporting System state-level panel for 1990–2010. Standard deviations are in parentheses. Alcohol involvement is likely measured with error (Eisenberg 2003), and the possibility exists that some states collected information on BAC levels more diligently than others.16 Focusing on nighttime and weekend fatal crashes can provide additional insight into the role of alcohol and help address the mea- surement error issue. As noted by Dee (1999), a substantial proportion of fatal crashes on weekends and at night involve alcohol. As of 2011, 75 percent of the patients on the Arizona medical marijuana registry were male; 69 percent of the patients on the Colorado registry were male. There is also evidence that many medical marijuana patients are below the age of 40. Forty-eight percent of registered patients in Montana and 42 percent of registered patients in Arizona were between the ages of 18 and 40; the average age of registered patients in Colorado was 40.17 To the extent that registered patients below the age of 40 are more likely to use
  • 77. medical marijuana recreationally, heterogeneous effects across the age distribution might be expected. Figures 1–3 compare pre- and postlegalization traffic fatality trends by age 16 We also experimented with calculating the alcohol-related fatality rates with the imputed BAC levels available in the FARS data. These estimates, which are similar in terms of magnitude and precision to those presented here, are available on request. See Adams, Blackburn, and Cotti (2012) for a discussion of the BAC imputation method. 17 For links to state registry data, see NORML, Medical Marijuana (http://norml.org/index.cfm ?Group_IDp3391). This content downloaded from 130.166.3.5 on Tue, 18 Nov 2014 03:00:05 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions http://norml.org/index.cfm?Group_ID=3391 http://norml.org/index.cfm?Group_ID=3391 http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp 344 The Journal of LAW & ECONOMICS Figure 1. Pre- and postlegalization trends in traffic fatality rates, ages 15–19 Figure 2. Pre- and postlegalization trends in traffic fatality rates, ages 20–39
  • 78. group.18 In each figure, the solid line represents the average traffic fatality rate for the treated states (those that legalized medical marijuana). The dashed line represents the average fatality rate for the control states (those that did not legalize medical marijuana). Year 0 on the horizontal axis represents the year in which legalization took place. Control states were randomly assigned a year of legalization between 1996 and 2010. 18 Figures 1–3 are based on FARS data for the period 1990– 2010. Fatality rates are expressed relative to year �1 and are weighted by the relevant population in state s and year t. This content downloaded from 130.166.3.5 on Tue, 18 Nov 2014 03:00:05 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp Medical Marijuana Laws 345 Figure 3. Pre- and postlegalization trends in traffic fatality rates, ages 40 and older Among teenagers (ages 15–19), young adults (ages 20–39), and older adults (ages 40 and above), average traffic fatality rates in the treated states closely follow those in the control states through year �1. This finding is important
  • 79. because it suggests that legalization was not preceded by, for instance, new anti- drunk-driving policies, increased spending on law enforcement, or highway im- provements. In the years immediately after legalization, average traffic fatality rates in MML states fall faster than average traffic fatality rates in the control states. This divergence is most pronounced among those 20–39. Among teenagers and older adults, average traffic fatality rates in the MML states converge with average traffic fatality rates in the control states 4–5 years after legalization. 4.2. The Empirical Model To further explore the relationship between legalization and traffic fatalities, we estimate the following baseline equation: ln(Fatalities Total ) p b � b MML � X b � v � w � � , (2)st 0 1 st st 2 s t st where s indexes states and t indexes years. The coefficient of interest, b1, represents the effect of legalizing medical marijuana.19 In alternative specifications, we re- place Fatalities Totalst with the remaining outcomes listed in Table 4. The vector Xst is composed of the controls described in Table 5, and vs and wt are state and year fixed effects, respectively. Previous studies provide evidence that a variety of state-level policies can impact traffic fatalities.
  • 80. For instance, graduated driver-licensing regulations and stricter seat belt laws are associated 19 This specification is based on Dee (2001), who examined the relationship between .08 BAC laws (making it illegal for drivers to have a BAC of .08 percent or higher) and traffic fatalities. This content downloaded from 130.166.3.5 on Tue, 18 Nov 2014 03:00:05 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp T ab le 5 In d ep en d en t V ar ia