SlideShare a Scribd company logo
1 of 22
Download to read offline
bcc consulting was founded in 2004 with the goal of integrating the art
and science of healthcare. Despite healthcare’s dependence on technology,
far too few organizations understand how to integrate new technologies
into clinical practice - beginning with challenges related to system
evaluation, selection, and contract negotiation, and finally culminating in
system implementation.
Over the last few years, client necessity has required us to expand
our offerings into business operations, primarily related to financial
management and strategic planning, but also encompassing key tactical
projects, such as sales and marketing campaigns.
The bottom line: results.
Copyright © 2008 bcc: Consulting. All Rights Reserved. 3
Practicing to Win
I have spent
the last three years
running my own “lab”
— actually, it’s a primary care medical office. I describe it as a “lab” because
I am first an owner in the business, and second the sole arbiter of our
operational methodologies – or at least for all things business-related.
Having spent several years working for a successful healthcare IT start-up,
before starting my own healthcare consulting company, I thought it was a
perfect opportunity to put my money with mouth and help my wife start
her own Family Medicine practice. She was hesitant, having only practiced
for a year following residency, but was eager to “do things her way,” at
least regarding all things medical. I say this, because unlike the majority
of physicians I have worked with, she has a healthy appreciation of her
strengths and weaknesses.
Other than the typical challenges – such as contractors who miss their time
and budget estimates by more than 20% - I don’t think there was anything
uniquely difficult about our situation. We were opening our practice
between two of the country’s largest academic medical centers, one about
5 minutes away in one direction, and the other about 10 minutes in the
opposite. My wife’s former practice was a good 30 minute drive away, so,
other than a few die-hard patients, we were starting from scratch.
Luckily the debt markets were much friendlier back then. Despite a few
sideways looks about starting a new practice between the two monolithic
academic medical centers, the banks were all-too-happy to lend us the
money to start the practice.
w w w . h i t b c c . c o m4
Our most important front-end decisions
EMR/PMS
My wife, having always used them, was more than comfortable employing
one. Furthermore, other than a few reasonable parameters, she left the
decision mostly up to me. I was very comfortable making this decision
because I had worked very closely with many of the companies we were
evaluating and knew their products quite well. In all honesty, the decision
was a fairly simple one. We selected eClinicalWorks (eCW), a very small
company in 2004, and today probably the dominant company in the
integrated EMR/PMS market.
Marketing
Relative to most medical offices, we have done a lot of it.
IPA Membership
As an existing member in an independent physician association (IPA), my
wife was able to bring her membership with her to the new practice.
Results
We started our practice with less than 30 patients, and 1 physician. Today,
we have 3 physicians working an approximate 2.5 FTE (full-time equivalent)
schedule, and a rapidly expanding patient-base currently around 4,500.
Supporting our physicians, we have 1 LPN, 1 clinical assistant, 1.5 FTE front-
office staff, and a part-time office manager (me).
Our practice was cash flow positive with the physicians averaging 12.5
patients/day on their work days; this occurred approximately 19 months
into operation. Our third year in business was profitable, and we expect
our profitability to continue to grow. Our physicians currently average
over 16 patients/day and we will continue to grow until we reach about 20
patients/day.
Early Assumptions
I earned an MBA with a concentration in Finance from the University of
Chicago, Graduate School of Business. I say this simply to give credibility
to my financial assumptions and to further add that becoming an “Office
Manager” was never my ultimate goal.
With the continuing pressure on medicine, particularly primary care, it
seems a fair question to ask why anyone would choose to start a primary
care medical practice. My instinctive beliefs are founded in Albert
Einstein’s famous saying, “In the midst of chaos lies opportunity.”
To explain that a little more clearly, I think it is impossible to graduate
from Chicago (a bastion of conservative financial theory) and not walk
“In the midst of chaos
lies opportunity.”
— Albert Einstein
Copyright © 2008 bcc: Consulting. All Rights Reserved. 5
Practicing to Win
away with a firmly ingrained belief in efficient markets. A principle that
does not say markets are always efficient, but that they tend towards
efficiency…in the long run. Short-term inefficiencies frequently exist.
To go a little further, while there are clearly pressures on medicine, and
primary care in particular, I was betting that the markets would eventually
correct themselves. Furthermore, as bad as things get, neither the
government nor the larger society will allow the 600,000 or so primary care
physicians working in small practices to go out of business. That’s not to
say that none will, but not all or even most.
In a deranged sort of way, it’s like the joke about the two campers in the
woods who hear a Grizzly outside their tent. One starts to put his running
shoes on and the other says, “You know, you can’t outrun a bear.” To which
his sneaker-donning “friend” replies, “I know, I just have to outrun you.”
The System allows for poor management. If it didn’t, there would be far
fewer doctors. In fact, I was willing to bet that if we performed in the top
5%, we could make a very good living. Nothing I have seen or learned has
changed this impression.
Medical Practice as Factory
First off, I am advocating for no such thing. I think comparing a medical
practice to a factory may help explain things in a way people can more
intuitively understand.
To start with, let’s go ahead and call medical treatment, or care, the
omnipresent “widget”. For arguments sake, let’s assume that every widget
is exactly the same, regardless of who the physician or where the practice.
In order to produce widgets, medical practices are assembled as factories.
Just as factories incur operating costs, so too do medical practices. We
generally refer to these operating costs as our overhead, which is broken
into two distinct categories: fixed costs, and variable costs.
As long as we are in the business of making and selling undifferentiated
widgets, we are completely subject to the price the market sets for
widgets—in economic terms, we are “price-takers.” Our goal in making
widgets is not to make “better” widgets, but rather to reduce our cost for
producing widgets, to sell more of them, or better, a combination of the
two – make them cheaper and sell more.
The System allows for
poor management. If it
didn’t, there would be
far fewer doctors.
w w w . h i t b c c . c o m6
Before I explain how to accomplish this, I have to address the cacophony of
upset readers who are protesting that, “We are most certainly not in the
business of making widgets!”
Let me assure you, you are. Who sets your prices? Do they differentiate
the same type and level of service based on quality? If you are inclined
to ask why payers reimburse different physicians and groups differently
for the same service, I assure you it has nothing to do with quality. It is
entirely driven by volume. Those with the most leverage, in terms of most
physicians treating the most number of patients, will nearly always be paid
more, regardless of quality.
Without getting into a completely separate discussion of pay for
performance, let me just say that it’s not happening any time soon, and it
will not be led by the government or by payers. I will get back to this point
later.
Certainly not all physicians are equal, and in turn not all service is equal.
No one would dispute that. Is quality a necessary component of the
product? Undeniably; however, this is a world of business, and in the world
of business no one is currently placing a premium on quality1
.
1
	 Or at least no one participating in the traditional system of healthcare.
New models such as concierge medicine, arguably come much closer to a
quality-based reward system.
S
D
P*
Industry Demand Curve
The traditional demand curves apply
to an entire industry in a competitive
market.
Firm Demand Curve
A competitive firm supplies only a
fraction of the total industry supply.
As a result, the demand curve of a
single firm in a competitive industry
is perfectly elastic (a horizontal line),
showing that the price remains fixed
regardless of the individual firm’s
supply—the firm is a price taker.
Copyright © 2008 bcc: Consulting. All Rights Reserved. 7
Practicing to Win
In fact, while it may sound cruel and heartless, any physician who offers
more than the “standard of care” and spends any extra time evaluating
or discussing anything outside of the current billable visit is a bad
businessman. By this measure, our physicians, like nearly all others are
bad business people. Again and again, physicians – and none more than
primary care – are asked to subsidize the larger system by freely making
sacrifices. Give us quality while we pay you in bulk.
So, in our widget producing factory, we are left with many, many
imperfections – areas that we cannot systematize or automate, chiefly the
machine otherwise known as physician. Luckily there are a number of
other areas that we can improve to 1: reduce the cost of the widget, and
2: sell more.
Fewer People
The greatest cost component of
any practice’s overhead is staff. I
have met so many practices that are
quick to lament the current state
of medicine while trying to run
their office as though they were in
the 1970’s. Even small offices have
staff dedicated to pulling charts.
Multiple front-office, back-office,
you name it.
I am a huge proponent of
technology and electronic medical
records (EMRs) in particular. Overall
EMR adoption is finally taking off,
but just as quickly we are hearing
distressing reports of the growing
number of failed implementations
and practices removing “useless”
systems. I would readily argue that any practice who has failed with an
EMR has failed with their deployment execution.
Any of the top 20 systems on the market are very good, and all have been
implemented in at least several hundred medical practices (the larger
vendors, in several thousand). Despite that every physician and every
office thinks they are singly unique, they are not. A deployment failure is
a commitment failure. And most frequently, the commitment failing is a
practice or a physician’s decision not to pay for good help.
A good integrated EMR and practice management system (PMS) exists in
the small office for one reason – to reduce office overhead. It is a tool that
helps you accomplish more with less.
I would readily argue
that any practice who
has failed with an EMR
has failed with their
deployment execution.
w w w . h i t b c c . c o m8
Offices that have been in practice for a number of years will spend the
money on an EMR, and because of loyalty to their staff, will not eliminate
positions. Again, I understand the loyalty, but please do not turn around
and complain that you are not getting the return on your investment.
Almost as annoying is to hear physicians talking about how electronic
medical records should improve patient care, or the patient experience –
with complete obliviousness to the business implications. Do not buy an
EMR to yet further improve the quality of the widgets you are selling—this
makes no sense, economically. Worse, it leads to the idiotic conclusion that
payers or hospitals or employers should pay for your EMR. Good luck with
that.
The fact is that EMRs do much to improve healthcare quality, but that
is an added benefit, and in today’s environment, not a reason to buy
one. First and foremost, they allow you to do more with less…Less people,
which is the best thing you can do to decrease the cost of a widget.
To give you an example, I submit
most claims on the same day
patients are seen, though from
time to time, I have to ask the
providers to finish an outstanding
note. As part of the note, each
physician is responsible for their
own coding. Again, no extra
personnel dedicated to roles
handled by our system. In addition
to the administrative edits,
eClinicalWorks now offers access to
CodeCorrect’s knowledge base (a
company focused on automating
the overwhelming ICD-9, CPT,
and HCPCS changes along with
government and private payer
rules related to them). I had
petitioned eClinicalWorks for 2
years to incorporate CodeCorrect’s edits and am glad they finally did as I
find it invaluable.
It takes me about 15 minutes a day to submit all of our charges
(approximately 40-60 claims). Each claim goes through the following
process before it reaches the payer: coded by physician, checked for
administrative errors by eCW, checked for potential coding violations
by CodeCorrect, reviewed and edited by me if necessary and sent to our
clearinghouse, Emdeon (formerly WebMD Envoy); the clearinghouse
performs an additional edit before submitting to the payer. If the
clearinghouse detects any errors, it will send a message to the office within
a few hours so the claim can be corrected and resubmitted before it is sent
to the payer, thus reducing a lengthy denial cycle.
Do not buy an EMR
to yet further improve
the quality of the
widgets you are selling
— this makes no sense,
economically.
Copyright © 2008 bcc: Consulting. All Rights Reserved. 9
Practicing to Win
The amazing efficiency of this process ensures claims are submitted
promptly and accurately, minimizing later follow up. It’s a great concept:
if you do it correctly the first time, you don’t have to have a dedicated staff
to follow up on denials.
The corollary to this is that when we do have denials, I can make the
decision to follow up or not. It’s a crazy notion, but not all denials are
worth following up on. I have no doubt that many other practices are
better chasing down every cent, but our goal is to optimize our resources
and return on investment.
Less Space
Rent or mortgage payments are likely any given practice’s second largest
regularly recurring cost item. In theory, as is true with leasing vs. buying
cars, there really shouldn’t be a financial difference between renting vs.
owning. Of course, as with all things, short-term inefficiencies abound.
Additionally, there are subtle trade-offs between owning and renting that
generally come with implicit price tags. For instance, renting offers the
added flexibility of moving later if you need additional space to grow into.
Therefore, you may be willing to pay more for the “option” that renting
offers.
For simplicity’s sake, let’s just assume that it’s a zero sum gain, monthly rent
vs. monthly mortgage. Let’s assume that you have a fixed amount of space
for which you pay a fixed monthly amount. Are you fully utilizing that
space? Are you maximizing your office’s ability to generate revenue?
I was recently informed that the average physician should have about 1,500
sq. ft. So, in other words, a 3 physician practice should be about 4,500 sq.
ft. Don’t get me wrong, I love data, lots of it. I love doing analysis on data.
But this underscores a problem that is so typical of practice management.
It reminds me of the story I once heard from a McKinsey or BCG consultant
who, in complete admiration of his boss, told the story of how she
informed a client that “on average, every person has one testicle and one
breast,” clearly admonishing the use of meaningless statistics.
Our office that originally supported a solo physician can now support 3 FTE
physicians. We occupy a whopping 2,000 sq. ft. – that’s less than 700 sq. ft.
per provider. Furthermore, we have ample space. I give my wife full credit
for the office design. She is inherently a utilitarian and designed 6 exam
rooms around a central work area. The back office that used to belong to
just me, is now shared by the 3 physicians and me.
The truth is that the physicians do not need an office, or at least an office
in the traditional sense. If anything, an office gives one an opportunity
to accumulate junk and personal odds and ends that are not even good
enough to be kept at home. If the providers are seeing patients – in the
exam rooms – they really do not need an office to hang out in. A chair, a
It’s a crazy notion,
but not all denials are
worth following up on.
w w w . h i t b c c . c o m10
desk, a computer to document ongoing encounters… not much else.
In fact, while the 4 of us share a single office, you will rarely find more than
2 people in the office at any given time. I suspect the average occupancy is
about 1.3.
Of course, we do not have hundreds of square feet dedicated to paper
charts. We also do not transcribe notes. I know that most EMRs support
transcription – no doubt an early concession to those physicians who
refused to change their ways – but it flies in the face of EMRs and adds a
completely unnecessary cost.
Perhaps one of the reasons that the office accommodates the four of us so
easily is that I actually spend very little time in the office at all. I perform
most of my management responsibilities from home or on the road via
VPN (virtual private network) access. Additionally, each of our physicians
has remote access to the server from home. If anyone is at the office after
5:15pm, it is because they choose to finish their notes in the quiet of the
office.
Greater Productivity
Thus far, we have reduced the cost of our widget by minimizing support
staff and maximizing the production capacity of our factory. There are
a number of other things that we can do to minimize additional cost
elements, but rather than address them individually, I would prefer to
address them as one group under the heading — When to Spend vs.
When to Skimp.
In general, both my wife and I are big believers in sweat equity – a roll-
up the sleeves, can-do attitude that can save money at just about every
turn. For example, we purchased the majority of our office equipment,
including exam tables, exam lights, a baby scale, and an autoclave, among
other items, from a defunct medical practice in town. We bought most
of our office furniture from an unfinished wood furniture store, that we
subsequently finished ourselves. Trust me, there was real sweat involved in
this.
But knowing when to roll up the sleeves, and when to take out the check
book is imperative. In fact, I lump so many different cost items into this
header because it is probably the one area where most practices make their
biggest mistake.
When we built-out our office, I paid the builders to pull Cat 5 cable
through our space, but I did all the technical work to punch down the
cable and ultimately build out our entire network – the heart and soul of
our operation. As soon as I was finished putting the whole thing together,
I immediately contracted with an excellent network support group,
UnlimitedPlus, to manage my network, specifically to provide continuous
monitoring and disaster recovery services. Why? Because I am not an
Knowing when
to roll up the sleeves,
and when to take
out the check book is
imperative.
Copyright © 2008 bcc: Consulting. All Rights Reserved. 11
Practicing to Win
expert network administrator. Furthermore, it took me 2 weeks, with help,
to get the network up and running. If it fails, I want it up and running
within 6 hours. This means having contingency servers, client PCs, network
switches, and routers on hand, and the ability to recreate my network
environment. I am proud of myself for putting the network together in
the first place. I am much smarter and more effective in troubleshooting
and solving problems on my own as a result; however, I recognize when to
call in the experts.
For not a whole lot more than we spend on our cleaning service, we have
remote data back-up and a solid contingency plan in place. What’s more,
I sleep comfortably each night knowing that if anything goes wrong with
either our system or our network, we will have it all up and running within
a day. Many practices are reluctant to pay for this type or level of service.
Another common problem I’ve already alluded to, and one that I speak
about often, is EMR/PMS vendor selection. When it comes to selecting an
EMR and practice management system (PMS), offices seem to think that as
long as they choose “the right” vendor, all of their problems will be solved.
In truth, any of the top vendors’ systems are adequate, some better than
others, and some much more expensive. The success or failure of an EMR/
PMS implementation has much more to do with the office’s network (IT
infrastructure) and its staff’s willingness and ability to adapt to change
(change management). Do not expect that simply choosing a vendor will
ensure success. It won’t.
Every decision involving resource utilization – chiefly physician and staff
time – must be weighed against its opportunity cost. In other words, how
else might that resource be deployed, or what else might that person be
doing?
Physicians are often referred to as bad business people. While somewhat
deserved, the reputation really comes from the fact that very few
physicians are formally schooled in business, and many physicians have
type-A personalities. They are generally intelligent, self-reliant, and
confident. These are great characteristics, but do not lend well to taking
advice. Even worse, they seem to imbue many physicians with the
intellectual curiosity and problem-solving to want to personally undertake
unnecessary challenges. Interestingly enough, this self-sufficiency does
not generally spill over into menial tasks like cleaning the office, or trade-
specific specialties like accounting or law.
Business acumen, strategic planning, management and to a large extent
computers and computer networking, on the other hand, are all egalitarian
undertakings that require no formal license or degree to practice. As a
result, those with proven academic success and intelligence are wont to
engage in them with surety and confidence. The cost of such erroneous
misjudgment is twofold: first, subpar business performance, and second,
either lost or interrupted time with patients, which hampers revenue-
generation.
Every decision involving
resource utilization —
chiefly physician and
staff time — must be
weighed against its
opportunity cost.
w w w . h i t b c c . c o m12
Know when to roll-up the sleeves and when to pay for good help, and
apply frequently in all business undertakings.
Greater Throughput
In maximizing the capacity of our office (which effectively lowers our per-
unit cost by increasing output without increasing fixed costs), we create an
environment that allows us to sell additional widgets. In other words, our
factory can now support greater throughput, but we still need to develop
the customer base or demand to offset this new supply.
Many practices, particularly well-established practices, have a surplus of
demand and can accommodate the new supply quite readily. Others need
to be a bit more aggressive and proactive in soliciting new patients. There
are a number of effective, low-cost ways to do this. Again, one of the main
objections to tasteful marketing is cost. Why spend money soliciting new
patients when you will eventually stop accepting them? There is a very
good reason for doing so.
Again, think of your office as a factory. You are spending X dollars a
month to run the factory, of which the vast majority of your costs are fixed
Why spend money
soliciting new patients
when you will eventually
stop accepting them?
TC TRTC TRTC
TT
A A firm’s total cost (TC) curve typi-
cally resembles a classic s-curve. Total
costs quickly rise with each incremen-
tal unit of output, reflecting an initial
outlay of fixed costs. As the costs
amortize over a higher quantity of
output, the marginal cost (or cost for
each additional unit) – or the slope
of the TC curve – decreases until it
nearly plateaus. Eventually the firm’s
ability to generate additional units
increasingly depends on higher vari-
able costs, causing the curve to slope
steeply upwards.
B As a price taker, the competitive
firm’s total revenue (TR) increases
along a diagonal line, the marginal
revenue is a constant slope.
C Total Profit is simply total rev-
enue minus total cost. This can be
expressed as TR – TC = TT (profit). The
maximum profit occurs at q* where
the distance between the two curves
is greatest.
Copyright © 2008 bcc: Consulting. All Rights Reserved. 13
Practicing to Win
and not variable. This creates what is known as “stickiness.” In other
words, you may be able to scale back blocks of cost to cut back the output
capacity of your factory. But you probably can do this at only certain points
along your supply curve. For instance, you may only be able to spend .8X
to run the factory at 80%, or .5X to run it at 50%. However, your overhead
is not perfectly variable like the fine tuning volume knob on your stereo.
This means that you are most likely paying X dollars to support 100%
capacity, even if your throughput is only 85%. Analysis of the situation
might reveal that you should actually lower your capacity to 80% so that
you can align your cost structure with your utilization – it may be better to
spend .8X for 80% than X for 85%.
The opposite is also true. If you are spending X, but running at 85%, you
should work to increase your capacity to 100%; but how hard? It depends.
How much are you losing by not running at 100%? You may currently be
profitable, but the inefficiency is undoubtedly costing you. The value of
the ongoing loss will give you a much better understanding of the need
to accelerate supply optimization. For example, how much should you be
willing to spend on a 6 month marketing campaign that will reduce your
under utilization from 12 months to 6?
A By comparison, if we assume
that all of our costs are fixed, we can
clearly see that our total cost (TC)
curve looks like a staircase – a fixed
level of cost supports a specific level
of output, beyond which point, the
marginal cost is the entire cost of the
next level of fixed costs.
B Again, as a price-taker, our total
revenue (TR) curve resembles the
typical competitive firm.
C Unlike the typical competitive
firm, which has a single point of
maximum profitability, we have
multiple points. This clearly shows
the importance of “right-sizing” your
clinical operation to match patient
load.
TC TRTC TRTC
TT1
TT2
TT3
q1
q2
q3
w w w . h i t b c c . c o m14
Realizing that the concept of stickiness can be confusing, let me explain
this further using a hypothetical medical practice example. Let’s assume
that we have a 5,000 sq. ft. office with the following parameters:
Rent 5,000 square feet
($10,000 a month)
+ 4 FTE Providers
($10,000 a month per provider)
+ 4 MAs
($2,500 per month per MA)
+ 3 Front-Office
($2,000 per month each)
+ 1 Back-Office
($3,000 per month)
+ 1 Office Manager
($6,000 per month)
=
Total Fixed Cost
$75,000 per month
=
Total Capacity
100 patients per day
=
Average collection per patient encounter
$90
What should we do, if anything, to run more optimally if we are only
seeing 85 patients a day?
First off, let’s calculate the value of our underutilization:
100 patient capacity
- 85 patients per day (current level)
= 15 patients per day
15 patients per day
x $90/encounter
= $1,350 per day
x 21 work days per month
= $28,350 month
That’s a lot of money, but keep in mind we are a full 15% underutilized.
Copyright © 2008 bcc: Consulting. All Rights Reserved. 15
Practicing to Win
People, as with most fixed costs, are fixed in the short-term but variable in
the long. In other words, if we know that we are going to be running at
85% of capacity for the foreseeable future, we can restructure our staffing
to reduce costs and capacity. However, if the shortfall is only temporary, it
is much more difficult to lay people off and rehire them only when they are
needed (also called furloughing). Factoring in the costs of finding, hiring
and training personnel, you can see why they are regarded as a fixed cost
in the short-term.
In our example, if we assume each physician has the exact same level of
productivity, reducing our provider staff from 4 to 3 would immediately
reduce our capacity by 25%. We would then be able to reduce some of
the support staff and our overall fixed monthly costs. The net effect may
actually be better than our starting point, but let’s assume we are growing,
and our goal is not to downsize.
A better alternative is to build-in some variability within our staffing. So,
rather than having 4 providers who must maintain full-time positions, it is
preferable to have at least one or two providers who have the flexibility to
work a part-to-full time schedule. This gives us the ability to ratchet down
our supply to better reflect demand.
The same is true of our medical assistants (MAs). So, instead of having
4 full-time MAs, we may prefer to have 3 full time and 2 part-time. The
part-time employees, in addition to giving us greater work-hour flexibility,
simultaneously reduce our overall benefits burden.
Basic Economic Theory
According to Wikipedia,
“microeconomics is a branch
of economics that studies how
individuals, households, and firms
make decisions to allocate limited
resources, typically in markets
where goods or services are being
bought and sold. Microeconomics
examines how these decisions and
behaviors affect the supply and
demand for goods and services,
which determines prices; and how
prices, in turn, determine the
supply and demand of goods and
services.”
In general “micro,” is extremely
intuitive and explains so much
about how and why people do
what they do. I believe that if
every physician were trained on
just two simple microeconomic
concepts they would be much
better business people –the first,
which I have already touched upon,
is opportunity cost and the second
is sunk cost.
Opportunity cost is simply the cost
or value that would be realized
if the resources required for the
contemplated undertaking were
otherwise deployed. In other
words, say a physician spends
30 minutes trying to configure a
network printer. Had he opted
instead to see 2 patients, he could
have potentially billed $500 in
charges, and collected $300. His
opportunity cost is $300. Rather
than trying to fix the printer
himself, he could have hired a
professional to fix the printer
for $50. So, while the physician
probably felt he was saving $50, he
really lost $250.
As its name suggests, opportunity
cost assumes an “opportunity.”
The physician’s time cannot
generically be expressed as $300
per 30 minutes or $600 an hour.
Such reasoning would prevent our
physician from doing anything but
seeing patients. Just because the
physician has 30 minute periods
where he can earn $300, does
not mean that every 30 minutes
of his time is worth $300. If,
for instance, he had no other
patients to see at 5:30pm, it may
be more advantageous to take
out the garbage and sweep and
mop the office floors if the only
other alternative were to sit and
do nothing. (Though, sitting and
doing nothing, in turn, has its own
value that is harder to compute
and may ultimately be more
valuable than the $20 of cleaning
services saved.)
continued on page 16
w w w . h i t b c c . c o m16
Structuring our staff in this manner will not increase our supply, but it will
lower our monthly costs by smoothing our cost curve.
For example, assume we can reduce both physician and MA staffing levels
to 90%. This reduces physician salaries by $4,000 per month and MA salary
by another $1,000. So, while we still have excess capacity, we have reduced
our fixed costs by $5,000 (not including any potential benefits reductions).
If instead, we decided to actively market for additional patients, how much
should we be willing to spend? Using our previous assumptions that our
shortfall would naturally be filled over the course of a year (through word
of mouth, insurance directories, etc…), the value of the loss would equal:
The point is that opportunity cost
is dynamic and requires continuous
reevaluation. Activities that during
one interval may have a negative
value can in another prove positive.
Sunk costs, on the other hand,
are non-recoverable costs. A
commonly used example is that of
a non-refundable movie ticket. If
a person buys a non-refundable
ticket and decides at some point
during the movie that she is
not enjoying it, she should only
consider her opportunity cost and
not the sunk cost of the movie
ticket. In other words, the $7.50
for the ticket is gone. If she had
the opportunity to do something
else that would be preferable to
sitting through a bad movie, she
should do it. To do otherwise
because of a mistaken belief that
leaving early would somehow be
“losing” the $7.50 is known as the
sunk cost fallacy. The money was
gone at the moment the ticket was
purchased, and should not be a
factor in any future decision.
As applied to medical practice
management, a common
example of the sunk cost fallacy
is a practice’s decision to keep
“plugging-away” on the same
old computer system that it has
been using for the last 10 years
(most likely a legacy practice
management system). The
argument that it has already been
paid for has zero implications in
calculating net present value (NPV)
– the fundamental benchmark for
any decision.
By definition, “NPV is a standard
method for the financial appraisal
of long-term projects. Used for
capital budgeting, and widely
throughout economics, it measures
the excess or shortfall of cash
flows, in present value terms, once
financing charges are met.”
ALL decisions should involve an
NPV calculation, whether formal
or informal. Those with a positive
value should be undertaken,
and those with a negative value
should not. At no point in an NPV
calculation should you consider
previous, unrecoverable, or sunk,
costs.
In fact, if you spent $10,000 on a
system as recently as yesterday (and
for simplicity’s sake assume
TRTC
a
By building a degree of variability
into our staffing, we can smooth our
total cost (TC) curve as shown. The
net effect is smaller negative profit-
ability (area a) and greater positive
profitability (area b).
continued on page 17
Copyright © 2008 bcc: Consulting. All Rights Reserved. 17
Practicing to Win
$28,350 per month
x 12 months
= $340,200
÷ 2 (assuming patient growth is
equally distributed over 12 months)
= $170,100
By comparison, if we were able to reduce the shortfall from 12 to 6
months, our loss would equal only:
$28,350 per month
x 6 months
= $170,100
÷ 2 (assuming patient growth is
equally distributed over 6 months)
= $85,050
This suggests that if we are able to run a marketing campaign that would
reduce the period of our patient shortfall from 12 to 6 months, we would
earn an additional $85,050. To put this
there are no recurring costs
associated with supporting the
system), and find a different system
today that costs say, $50,000, but
offers a positive NPV, then you
should purchase it. The system
you purchased yesterday has no
bearing on today’s decision. In
other words, you cannot make-up
for a previous poor decision by
“sticking it out.” The result of such
thinking is a multiplication of the
number and effect of your poor
decisions.
These economic concepts extend
well beyond easily calculable
monetary decisions. For example,
I would argue that the primary
reason there is so much resistance
to change is the sunk cost fallacy.
When presented with a new
system, policy, or procedure,
people resist change. While people
can be pig-headed, or “irrational”
as an economist would say, they
generally are not. The rash of
failures and challenges associated
with system change is not caused
by rampant irrationality, or
incompetence. Something else is
at play.
Whether the front-office
receptionist, the office manager,
or even the physician, each
person learned to do their job a
certain way. They invested time
and energy, and likely feel they
are proficient at accomplishing
their responsibilities, regardless
of whether true or not. The
point is that they believe they are
good at what they do. (Consider,
for example, that research has
consistently found that 9 out of 10
people believe they are smarter
than the average person.)
When confronted with change,
the near-universal reaction is that
the effort of learning something
new does not justify the cost.
The problem is that the person
making the decision typically
overvalues their current efficiency,
undervalues the potential gains
to be realized by changing (thus,
resulting in an understated NPV),
and finally cannot let go of the
original effort required to learn
their job in the first place (sunk
cost fallacy).
Nearly every decision in medical
practice management involves
these concepts and having a better
understanding of their implications
can greatly simplify and improve
decision-making.
continued on page 18
w w w . h i t b c c . c o m18
into perspective, an aggressive marketing campaign might cost $5,000 to
$10,000. So, to earn $85,000 at a cost of even $10,000 nets an additional
$75,000 of income.
Finally, with some basic principles in place, we can graphically display the
effect productivity enhancing tools and processes have on our cost curve
and ultimately profitability:
The Top-Line
Up to this point, we have focused on the lower half of the factory’s
income statement, or the expenses. Working in the perfectly competitive
commodity business of widgets, our ability to improve our performance
is primarily limited to the realm of cost and productivity management.
Remember, we are not setting the price of our goods, the market is.
After all the work we have discussed to run our factory as efficiently as
possible, what do you think the net difference is between the best and
worst performing practices? I would bet that, adjusting for outliers and
normalizing for comparison, the best practices earn 10% higher income as
a result of good practice management. 10% is substantial, particularly if it
all flows through to the bottom line.
Now, let’s relax our assumption that the market fixes the price of widgets.
It still does, but instead of a single price, let’s assume it fixes the price for
widgets at 3 distinct levels: 1 small independent practice, 2 moderate
group affiliated practice, and 3 large affiliated practice.
Small independent practices as the label describes are independent (not
group or hospital owned) and are typically comprised of 5 or fewer
physicians. Roughly 75% of all physicians practice in these groups.
Moderate group affiliated practices are either: a) larger group practices, b)
belong to a larger parent organization, or c) affiliate with enough practices
to form an association, such as an independent physician association (IPA).
Moderate group affiliated practices typically include anywhere from 50 to
The enhanced productivity provided
by an effective EMR/PMS increases
initial total cost (TC1 vs. TC0), but ex-
tends the reach of fixed cost tranches
– essentially, you can do more with
less. This graph is conceptual only
and not drawn to scale. The net
effect is greater total profitability
(areas under the TR curve) for TC1 vs.
TC0.
TC0
TC1
TR
Copyright © 2008 bcc: Consulting. All Rights Reserved. 19
Practicing to Win
several -hundred physicians, or more. A small independent practice can
gain leverage by joining such an association, as my wife’s practice has done.
Finally, the large affiliated practice is either part of a large hospital or
group affiliation that may have many thousands of physicians.
What do you think the market pays for widgets across these 3 groups?
Keep in mind that fee schedules are confidential, so not readily
comparable.
When the small independent practice “opts-in” to a payer’s contract, they
are given the most basic and lopsided fee schedule possible. Let’s just call
this Y per widget (our baseline).
With the added leverage of a moderate group affiliation the exact same
practice would likely see their fee schedule jump to somewhere between
1.15Y to 1.20Y – a 15%-20% increase.
The large affiliated practice, in turn, would likely see fee schedules in the
neighborhood of 1.2Y to 1.4Y – a 20% to 40% increase over the baseline!
Again, these different fee schedules have zero correlation to quality.
It should be very clear that while it is important to run a good practice
– a 10% differential is enormous ($100,000 to the bottom line for every
$1,000,000 of gross revenue) – it is more critical to get on the right
contracts. This should help explain to the casual observer how some
apparently well run practices have difficulty staying afloat, while other
clearly inefficient operations seem to thrive.
Keep in mind that this situation is not sustainable. Eventually, the market
will correct itself and those providing good, quality care will be justly
rewarded, and better so if they can also run a good business operation.
In the interim, practices must understand the dynamics of the current
environment if they are to succeed.
If the same firm, with the same cost
curve, were offered three different
fee schedules (total revenue curves),
the impact to total profitability is
represented by TT0
, TT1
, and TT2
.
TR0
TR1
TR2
TC
TT0
TT1
TT2
w w w . h i t b c c . c o m20
Future Challenges
Regardless of the appropriateness of the moniker “Consumer-Driven
Healthcare,” the shift of ultimate financial responsibility from employers
to employees, or healthcare consumers, brings with it both good and
bad. For one, quality cannot be driven by payers. There are far too many
variables and unknowns to effectively benchmark clinical outcomes. Worse
yet, allowing the payers to define the quality criteria and metrics is a bit
like having the foxes establish security protocols at the hen houses. Payers
are far more interested in and incentivized to maximize profitability than
improve clinical outcomes. Don’t let the fact that the two occasionally
intersect lead you to conclude otherwise.
As in all industries, the consumers of goods or services should be the ones
to determine the value of that which they seek. To assume that a third
party is better equipped to measure the quality of care provided than the
patient receiving the care is beyond paternalistic, and has consistently
proven inaccurate. I am much better equipped, for instance, to determine
the quality provided by my physician than my auto mechanic. But other
than industry self-regulation, which healthcare does as well, no outside
organization intervenes directly on my behalf to protect me from making a
bad auto repair decision or from being taken advantage of.
Ultimately, as patients become
more empowered to spend their
own dollars on healthcare, the
tried and true laws of supply
and demand will kick in. Good
physicians will be highly sought
after. Lesser physicians will be
in less demand, and the market
will adjust prices accordingly. The
platforms for consumers sharing
their experiences and feedback
have grown exponentially over
the last few years and will likely
continue as patients assume
more of their responsibilities as
consumers.
A short-term problem with the
newer healthcare financing model
is that more reimbursement is coming directly from the patient.   When you
consider that your worst payer is almost certainly your patients themselves
(consumer spending reports generally show that consumers place medical
bills somewhere between Ho-Hos and Ding-Dongs on their priority list
of debt repayment), practices must become more aggressive in verifying
benefit eligibility and collecting payment in advance of service.
As in all industries,
the consumers of goods
or services should be
the ones to determine
the value of that which
they seek.
Copyright © 2008 bcc: Consulting. All Rights Reserved. 21
Practicing to Win
Final Thoughts
Again, my rationale for comparing the physician office to a factory is in
no way intended to detract from the great care and sacrifice so many
countless physicians make day in and day out. To the contrary, I feel that
our healthcare system should reward those commensurate to the service
they provide, rather than arbitrarily, or even worse, politically.
Healthcare has historically fallen
into a special class of industry and
business that even in the eyes of the
staunchest laissez-faire economists
has deservedly required government
intervention and oversight. The
argument has long been based
on the notion of information
asymmetry – the physician or
provider has a disproportionate
knowledge or access to information
than the consumer. Thus, in
protecting the rights of the
consumer, the government is
justified in intervening to ensure a
level playing field.
It’s a reasonable concept, but
in practice, does not work. The
government is largely responsible
for the dysfunctional system that we
have today. Rather than embarking
on a tirade of Medicare and
Medicaid, I prefer to focus on those things that physicians and practices can
do to not only survive, but thrive.
Sound economic and financial practices can greatly improve any medical
practice, even in today’s managed care environment. As healthcare shifts
to a more traditional free-market system, understanding of economic
theory and principles will become even more pertinent and crucial.
The continued transformation of healthcare over the next decade promises
yet more chaos; but rather than throwing your hands up in resignation,
ponder Albert Einstein’s wisdom and appreciate the boundless opportunity
before us.
Unlimited Plus is North Carolina’s premier Healthcare IT Services Provider,
specializing in network management, EMR/PMS implementation and infor-
mation technology consulting services. With hundreds of machines under
management across healthcare organizations large and small, Unlimited
Plus consistently delivers high-quality and responsive technical support.
To learn more, visit us at http://www.unlimitedplus.com/Healthcare,
or call (888) 865-7587.

More Related Content

What's hot

[White Paper] Patient Engagement ROI
[White Paper] Patient Engagement ROI[White Paper] Patient Engagement ROI
[White Paper] Patient Engagement ROIUbiCare
 
Financially clearing patients is becoming an important part of revenue cycle ...
Financially clearing patients is becoming an important part of revenue cycle ...Financially clearing patients is becoming an important part of revenue cycle ...
Financially clearing patients is becoming an important part of revenue cycle ...Healthcare consultant
 
Maximizing Front Desk Collections W Next Gen (For Distribution).Ppt
Maximizing Front Desk Collections W Next Gen (For Distribution).PptMaximizing Front Desk Collections W Next Gen (For Distribution).Ppt
Maximizing Front Desk Collections W Next Gen (For Distribution).PptJames Muir
 

What's hot (8)

[White Paper] Patient Engagement ROI
[White Paper] Patient Engagement ROI[White Paper] Patient Engagement ROI
[White Paper] Patient Engagement ROI
 
OTMar10pg22
OTMar10pg22OTMar10pg22
OTMar10pg22
 
The new buyers of hospice under healthcare reform
The new buyers of hospice under healthcare reformThe new buyers of hospice under healthcare reform
The new buyers of hospice under healthcare reform
 
Anesthesia Business Consultants: Communique winter11
Anesthesia Business Consultants: Communique winter11Anesthesia Business Consultants: Communique winter11
Anesthesia Business Consultants: Communique winter11
 
Anesthesia Business Consultants: Communique spring09
Anesthesia Business Consultants: Communique spring09Anesthesia Business Consultants: Communique spring09
Anesthesia Business Consultants: Communique spring09
 
Financially clearing patients is becoming an important part of revenue cycle ...
Financially clearing patients is becoming an important part of revenue cycle ...Financially clearing patients is becoming an important part of revenue cycle ...
Financially clearing patients is becoming an important part of revenue cycle ...
 
Maximizing Front Desk Collections W Next Gen (For Distribution).Ppt
Maximizing Front Desk Collections W Next Gen (For Distribution).PptMaximizing Front Desk Collections W Next Gen (For Distribution).Ppt
Maximizing Front Desk Collections W Next Gen (For Distribution).Ppt
 
jeremypp2
jeremypp2jeremypp2
jeremypp2
 

Viewers also liked

Entreprenuership
EntreprenuershipEntreprenuership
Entreprenuershipjamal2222
 
Walt Disney Entreprenuership
Walt Disney EntreprenuershipWalt Disney Entreprenuership
Walt Disney Entreprenuershipmeminb
 
Navigate entreprenuership
Navigate entreprenuershipNavigate entreprenuership
Navigate entreprenuershipsinghnalin
 
Teaching Entreprenuership to a Digital Generation
Teaching Entreprenuership to a Digital GenerationTeaching Entreprenuership to a Digital Generation
Teaching Entreprenuership to a Digital GenerationRick Coplin
 
Ryan Eagle- Do you have what it takes to be an entreprenuership?
Ryan Eagle- Do you have what it takes to be an entreprenuership?Ryan Eagle- Do you have what it takes to be an entreprenuership?
Ryan Eagle- Do you have what it takes to be an entreprenuership?Ryan Eagle
 
A Resourced Based View of Entreprenuership
A Resourced Based View of EntreprenuershipA Resourced Based View of Entreprenuership
A Resourced Based View of EntreprenuershipFahim Akhtar
 
Introduction to CMU Lean Entreprenuership Course
Introduction to CMU Lean Entreprenuership CourseIntroduction to CMU Lean Entreprenuership Course
Introduction to CMU Lean Entreprenuership CourseSean Ammirati
 
Entreprenuership
EntreprenuershipEntreprenuership
EntreprenuershipJeetu Joshi
 
Entreprenuership: An Overview
Entreprenuership: An OverviewEntreprenuership: An Overview
Entreprenuership: An OverviewJitendra Sahoo
 
99 slideshares that every entrepreneur must read
99 slideshares that every entrepreneur must read99 slideshares that every entrepreneur must read
99 slideshares that every entrepreneur must readEric Tachibana
 
Entreprenuership By Jim Cox
Entreprenuership By  Jim  CoxEntreprenuership By  Jim  Cox
Entreprenuership By Jim CoxJim Cox
 
ENTREPRENEURSHIP- CONCEPT
ENTREPRENEURSHIP- CONCEPTENTREPRENEURSHIP- CONCEPT
ENTREPRENEURSHIP- CONCEPTCHARAK RAY
 
Entrepreneurship powerpoint slide
Entrepreneurship powerpoint slideEntrepreneurship powerpoint slide
Entrepreneurship powerpoint slideMahlatsi Lerato
 

Viewers also liked (18)

Entreprenuership
EntreprenuershipEntreprenuership
Entreprenuership
 
Walt Disney Entreprenuership
Walt Disney EntreprenuershipWalt Disney Entreprenuership
Walt Disney Entreprenuership
 
Navigate entreprenuership
Navigate entreprenuershipNavigate entreprenuership
Navigate entreprenuership
 
Teaching Entreprenuership to a Digital Generation
Teaching Entreprenuership to a Digital GenerationTeaching Entreprenuership to a Digital Generation
Teaching Entreprenuership to a Digital Generation
 
Ryan Eagle- Do you have what it takes to be an entreprenuership?
Ryan Eagle- Do you have what it takes to be an entreprenuership?Ryan Eagle- Do you have what it takes to be an entreprenuership?
Ryan Eagle- Do you have what it takes to be an entreprenuership?
 
A Resourced Based View of Entreprenuership
A Resourced Based View of EntreprenuershipA Resourced Based View of Entreprenuership
A Resourced Based View of Entreprenuership
 
Introduction to CMU Lean Entreprenuership Course
Introduction to CMU Lean Entreprenuership CourseIntroduction to CMU Lean Entreprenuership Course
Introduction to CMU Lean Entreprenuership Course
 
Entreprenuership
EntreprenuershipEntreprenuership
Entreprenuership
 
Entreprenuership
EntreprenuershipEntreprenuership
Entreprenuership
 
Entreprenuership: An Overview
Entreprenuership: An OverviewEntreprenuership: An Overview
Entreprenuership: An Overview
 
Entreprenuership
EntreprenuershipEntreprenuership
Entreprenuership
 
personal mastery
personal masterypersonal mastery
personal mastery
 
Entreprenuership
EntreprenuershipEntreprenuership
Entreprenuership
 
Entrepreneurship
EntrepreneurshipEntrepreneurship
Entrepreneurship
 
99 slideshares that every entrepreneur must read
99 slideshares that every entrepreneur must read99 slideshares that every entrepreneur must read
99 slideshares that every entrepreneur must read
 
Entreprenuership By Jim Cox
Entreprenuership By  Jim  CoxEntreprenuership By  Jim  Cox
Entreprenuership By Jim Cox
 
ENTREPRENEURSHIP- CONCEPT
ENTREPRENEURSHIP- CONCEPTENTREPRENEURSHIP- CONCEPT
ENTREPRENEURSHIP- CONCEPT
 
Entrepreneurship powerpoint slide
Entrepreneurship powerpoint slideEntrepreneurship powerpoint slide
Entrepreneurship powerpoint slide
 

Similar to Practicing to Win

2013 HealthTech Conference Notes
2013 HealthTech Conference Notes2013 HealthTech Conference Notes
2013 HealthTech Conference NotesLindsay Meyer
 
The true cost of healthcare Printable copy
The true cost of healthcare Printable copyThe true cost of healthcare Printable copy
The true cost of healthcare Printable copydrbelk
 
Mintzberg managing the myths_of_health_care
Mintzberg managing the myths_of_health_careMintzberg managing the myths_of_health_care
Mintzberg managing the myths_of_health_careCarlo Favaretti
 
The Sustainable Health Care Facility of the FutureTextbooks H.docx
The Sustainable Health Care Facility of the FutureTextbooks H.docxThe Sustainable Health Care Facility of the FutureTextbooks H.docx
The Sustainable Health Care Facility of the FutureTextbooks H.docxchristalgrieg
 
Spotlight On... The Pharma Customer Experience
Spotlight On... The Pharma Customer ExperienceSpotlight On... The Pharma Customer Experience
Spotlight On... The Pharma Customer ExperienceCOUCH Health
 
Partnering with Health Systems: Potholes and Pitfalls on the road from Custom...
Partnering with Health Systems: Potholes and Pitfalls on the road from Custom...Partnering with Health Systems: Potholes and Pitfalls on the road from Custom...
Partnering with Health Systems: Potholes and Pitfalls on the road from Custom...Levi Shapiro
 
Partneringwithhealthsystemsfinal 180425103202
Partneringwithhealthsystemsfinal 180425103202Partneringwithhealthsystemsfinal 180425103202
Partneringwithhealthsystemsfinal 180425103202Daisuke Tanaka
 
Define the concept of an integrated physician model.” To defin.docx
Define the concept of an integrated physician model.” To defin.docxDefine the concept of an integrated physician model.” To defin.docx
Define the concept of an integrated physician model.” To defin.docxrandyburney60861
 
Respond to 2 students DQ 275 words and 1 reference eachOriginal .docx
Respond to 2 students DQ 275 words and 1 reference eachOriginal .docxRespond to 2 students DQ 275 words and 1 reference eachOriginal .docx
Respond to 2 students DQ 275 words and 1 reference eachOriginal .docxmackulaytoni
 
How to get more patients
How to get more patientsHow to get more patients
How to get more patientsSTEVE MOMIN
 
10 Biggest Market Access Mistakes
10 Biggest Market Access Mistakes10 Biggest Market Access Mistakes
10 Biggest Market Access MistakesCara Lacey
 
Why Medical Device Sales
Why Medical Device SalesWhy Medical Device Sales
Why Medical Device SalesDavid Bagga
 
Increasing the quality of clinical research: best ways to solve the most comm...
Increasing the quality of clinical research: best ways to solve the most comm...Increasing the quality of clinical research: best ways to solve the most comm...
Increasing the quality of clinical research: best ways to solve the most comm...TrialJoin
 
How to Get All the New Patients You Want...
How to Get All the New Patients You Want...How to Get All the New Patients You Want...
How to Get All the New Patients You Want...Claudio Gormaz
 
How to Get All the New Patients You Want...
How to Get All the New Patients You Want...How to Get All the New Patients You Want...
How to Get All the New Patients You Want...Steven Cox
 
Broker Article
Broker ArticleBroker Article
Broker Articlejeffmarks
 

Similar to Practicing to Win (20)

2013 HealthTech Conference Notes
2013 HealthTech Conference Notes2013 HealthTech Conference Notes
2013 HealthTech Conference Notes
 
The true cost of healthcare Printable copy
The true cost of healthcare Printable copyThe true cost of healthcare Printable copy
The true cost of healthcare Printable copy
 
Mintzberg managing the myths_of_health_care
Mintzberg managing the myths_of_health_careMintzberg managing the myths_of_health_care
Mintzberg managing the myths_of_health_care
 
Anesthesia Business Consultants Communique fall 2019
Anesthesia Business Consultants Communique fall 2019Anesthesia Business Consultants Communique fall 2019
Anesthesia Business Consultants Communique fall 2019
 
The Sustainable Health Care Facility of the FutureTextbooks H.docx
The Sustainable Health Care Facility of the FutureTextbooks H.docxThe Sustainable Health Care Facility of the FutureTextbooks H.docx
The Sustainable Health Care Facility of the FutureTextbooks H.docx
 
Healthcare Consumerism, Access & Engagement white paper
Healthcare Consumerism, Access & Engagement white paper Healthcare Consumerism, Access & Engagement white paper
Healthcare Consumerism, Access & Engagement white paper
 
Spotlight On... The Pharma Customer Experience
Spotlight On... The Pharma Customer ExperienceSpotlight On... The Pharma Customer Experience
Spotlight On... The Pharma Customer Experience
 
Partnering with Health Systems: Potholes and Pitfalls on the road from Custom...
Partnering with Health Systems: Potholes and Pitfalls on the road from Custom...Partnering with Health Systems: Potholes and Pitfalls on the road from Custom...
Partnering with Health Systems: Potholes and Pitfalls on the road from Custom...
 
Partneringwithhealthsystemsfinal 180425103202
Partneringwithhealthsystemsfinal 180425103202Partneringwithhealthsystemsfinal 180425103202
Partneringwithhealthsystemsfinal 180425103202
 
Summer 2015 Communique Newsletter
Summer 2015 Communique Newsletter Summer 2015 Communique Newsletter
Summer 2015 Communique Newsletter
 
Define the concept of an integrated physician model.” To defin.docx
Define the concept of an integrated physician model.” To defin.docxDefine the concept of an integrated physician model.” To defin.docx
Define the concept of an integrated physician model.” To defin.docx
 
Forbes Article 2014
Forbes Article 2014Forbes Article 2014
Forbes Article 2014
 
Respond to 2 students DQ 275 words and 1 reference eachOriginal .docx
Respond to 2 students DQ 275 words and 1 reference eachOriginal .docxRespond to 2 students DQ 275 words and 1 reference eachOriginal .docx
Respond to 2 students DQ 275 words and 1 reference eachOriginal .docx
 
How to get more patients
How to get more patientsHow to get more patients
How to get more patients
 
10 Biggest Market Access Mistakes
10 Biggest Market Access Mistakes10 Biggest Market Access Mistakes
10 Biggest Market Access Mistakes
 
Why Medical Device Sales
Why Medical Device SalesWhy Medical Device Sales
Why Medical Device Sales
 
Increasing the quality of clinical research: best ways to solve the most comm...
Increasing the quality of clinical research: best ways to solve the most comm...Increasing the quality of clinical research: best ways to solve the most comm...
Increasing the quality of clinical research: best ways to solve the most comm...
 
How to Get All the New Patients You Want...
How to Get All the New Patients You Want...How to Get All the New Patients You Want...
How to Get All the New Patients You Want...
 
How to Get All the New Patients You Want...
How to Get All the New Patients You Want...How to Get All the New Patients You Want...
How to Get All the New Patients You Want...
 
Broker Article
Broker ArticleBroker Article
Broker Article
 

More from David Brooks

PS Performance Evaluation
PS Performance EvaluationPS Performance Evaluation
PS Performance EvaluationDavid Brooks
 
qlqsmsinfographicfinal-1-120819134701-phpapp02
qlqsmsinfographicfinal-1-120819134701-phpapp02qlqsmsinfographicfinal-1-120819134701-phpapp02
qlqsmsinfographicfinal-1-120819134701-phpapp02David Brooks
 
Practice to Win w-Notes
Practice to Win w-NotesPractice to Win w-Notes
Practice to Win w-NotesDavid Brooks
 

More from David Brooks (6)

PS Performance Evaluation
PS Performance EvaluationPS Performance Evaluation
PS Performance Evaluation
 
qlqsmsinfographicfinal-1-120819134701-phpapp02
qlqsmsinfographicfinal-1-120819134701-phpapp02qlqsmsinfographicfinal-1-120819134701-phpapp02
qlqsmsinfographicfinal-1-120819134701-phpapp02
 
bccMRG-Q106
bccMRG-Q106bccMRG-Q106
bccMRG-Q106
 
GM06
GM06GM06
GM06
 
EMRGuide
EMRGuideEMRGuide
EMRGuide
 
Practice to Win w-Notes
Practice to Win w-NotesPractice to Win w-Notes
Practice to Win w-Notes
 

Practicing to Win

  • 1.
  • 2. bcc consulting was founded in 2004 with the goal of integrating the art and science of healthcare. Despite healthcare’s dependence on technology, far too few organizations understand how to integrate new technologies into clinical practice - beginning with challenges related to system evaluation, selection, and contract negotiation, and finally culminating in system implementation. Over the last few years, client necessity has required us to expand our offerings into business operations, primarily related to financial management and strategic planning, but also encompassing key tactical projects, such as sales and marketing campaigns. The bottom line: results.
  • 3. Copyright © 2008 bcc: Consulting. All Rights Reserved. 3 Practicing to Win I have spent the last three years running my own “lab” — actually, it’s a primary care medical office. I describe it as a “lab” because I am first an owner in the business, and second the sole arbiter of our operational methodologies – or at least for all things business-related. Having spent several years working for a successful healthcare IT start-up, before starting my own healthcare consulting company, I thought it was a perfect opportunity to put my money with mouth and help my wife start her own Family Medicine practice. She was hesitant, having only practiced for a year following residency, but was eager to “do things her way,” at least regarding all things medical. I say this, because unlike the majority of physicians I have worked with, she has a healthy appreciation of her strengths and weaknesses. Other than the typical challenges – such as contractors who miss their time and budget estimates by more than 20% - I don’t think there was anything uniquely difficult about our situation. We were opening our practice between two of the country’s largest academic medical centers, one about 5 minutes away in one direction, and the other about 10 minutes in the opposite. My wife’s former practice was a good 30 minute drive away, so, other than a few die-hard patients, we were starting from scratch. Luckily the debt markets were much friendlier back then. Despite a few sideways looks about starting a new practice between the two monolithic academic medical centers, the banks were all-too-happy to lend us the money to start the practice.
  • 4. w w w . h i t b c c . c o m4 Our most important front-end decisions EMR/PMS My wife, having always used them, was more than comfortable employing one. Furthermore, other than a few reasonable parameters, she left the decision mostly up to me. I was very comfortable making this decision because I had worked very closely with many of the companies we were evaluating and knew their products quite well. In all honesty, the decision was a fairly simple one. We selected eClinicalWorks (eCW), a very small company in 2004, and today probably the dominant company in the integrated EMR/PMS market. Marketing Relative to most medical offices, we have done a lot of it. IPA Membership As an existing member in an independent physician association (IPA), my wife was able to bring her membership with her to the new practice. Results We started our practice with less than 30 patients, and 1 physician. Today, we have 3 physicians working an approximate 2.5 FTE (full-time equivalent) schedule, and a rapidly expanding patient-base currently around 4,500. Supporting our physicians, we have 1 LPN, 1 clinical assistant, 1.5 FTE front- office staff, and a part-time office manager (me). Our practice was cash flow positive with the physicians averaging 12.5 patients/day on their work days; this occurred approximately 19 months into operation. Our third year in business was profitable, and we expect our profitability to continue to grow. Our physicians currently average over 16 patients/day and we will continue to grow until we reach about 20 patients/day. Early Assumptions I earned an MBA with a concentration in Finance from the University of Chicago, Graduate School of Business. I say this simply to give credibility to my financial assumptions and to further add that becoming an “Office Manager” was never my ultimate goal. With the continuing pressure on medicine, particularly primary care, it seems a fair question to ask why anyone would choose to start a primary care medical practice. My instinctive beliefs are founded in Albert Einstein’s famous saying, “In the midst of chaos lies opportunity.” To explain that a little more clearly, I think it is impossible to graduate from Chicago (a bastion of conservative financial theory) and not walk “In the midst of chaos lies opportunity.” — Albert Einstein
  • 5. Copyright © 2008 bcc: Consulting. All Rights Reserved. 5 Practicing to Win away with a firmly ingrained belief in efficient markets. A principle that does not say markets are always efficient, but that they tend towards efficiency…in the long run. Short-term inefficiencies frequently exist. To go a little further, while there are clearly pressures on medicine, and primary care in particular, I was betting that the markets would eventually correct themselves. Furthermore, as bad as things get, neither the government nor the larger society will allow the 600,000 or so primary care physicians working in small practices to go out of business. That’s not to say that none will, but not all or even most. In a deranged sort of way, it’s like the joke about the two campers in the woods who hear a Grizzly outside their tent. One starts to put his running shoes on and the other says, “You know, you can’t outrun a bear.” To which his sneaker-donning “friend” replies, “I know, I just have to outrun you.” The System allows for poor management. If it didn’t, there would be far fewer doctors. In fact, I was willing to bet that if we performed in the top 5%, we could make a very good living. Nothing I have seen or learned has changed this impression. Medical Practice as Factory First off, I am advocating for no such thing. I think comparing a medical practice to a factory may help explain things in a way people can more intuitively understand. To start with, let’s go ahead and call medical treatment, or care, the omnipresent “widget”. For arguments sake, let’s assume that every widget is exactly the same, regardless of who the physician or where the practice. In order to produce widgets, medical practices are assembled as factories. Just as factories incur operating costs, so too do medical practices. We generally refer to these operating costs as our overhead, which is broken into two distinct categories: fixed costs, and variable costs. As long as we are in the business of making and selling undifferentiated widgets, we are completely subject to the price the market sets for widgets—in economic terms, we are “price-takers.” Our goal in making widgets is not to make “better” widgets, but rather to reduce our cost for producing widgets, to sell more of them, or better, a combination of the two – make them cheaper and sell more. The System allows for poor management. If it didn’t, there would be far fewer doctors.
  • 6. w w w . h i t b c c . c o m6 Before I explain how to accomplish this, I have to address the cacophony of upset readers who are protesting that, “We are most certainly not in the business of making widgets!” Let me assure you, you are. Who sets your prices? Do they differentiate the same type and level of service based on quality? If you are inclined to ask why payers reimburse different physicians and groups differently for the same service, I assure you it has nothing to do with quality. It is entirely driven by volume. Those with the most leverage, in terms of most physicians treating the most number of patients, will nearly always be paid more, regardless of quality. Without getting into a completely separate discussion of pay for performance, let me just say that it’s not happening any time soon, and it will not be led by the government or by payers. I will get back to this point later. Certainly not all physicians are equal, and in turn not all service is equal. No one would dispute that. Is quality a necessary component of the product? Undeniably; however, this is a world of business, and in the world of business no one is currently placing a premium on quality1 . 1 Or at least no one participating in the traditional system of healthcare. New models such as concierge medicine, arguably come much closer to a quality-based reward system. S D P* Industry Demand Curve The traditional demand curves apply to an entire industry in a competitive market. Firm Demand Curve A competitive firm supplies only a fraction of the total industry supply. As a result, the demand curve of a single firm in a competitive industry is perfectly elastic (a horizontal line), showing that the price remains fixed regardless of the individual firm’s supply—the firm is a price taker.
  • 7. Copyright © 2008 bcc: Consulting. All Rights Reserved. 7 Practicing to Win In fact, while it may sound cruel and heartless, any physician who offers more than the “standard of care” and spends any extra time evaluating or discussing anything outside of the current billable visit is a bad businessman. By this measure, our physicians, like nearly all others are bad business people. Again and again, physicians – and none more than primary care – are asked to subsidize the larger system by freely making sacrifices. Give us quality while we pay you in bulk. So, in our widget producing factory, we are left with many, many imperfections – areas that we cannot systematize or automate, chiefly the machine otherwise known as physician. Luckily there are a number of other areas that we can improve to 1: reduce the cost of the widget, and 2: sell more. Fewer People The greatest cost component of any practice’s overhead is staff. I have met so many practices that are quick to lament the current state of medicine while trying to run their office as though they were in the 1970’s. Even small offices have staff dedicated to pulling charts. Multiple front-office, back-office, you name it. I am a huge proponent of technology and electronic medical records (EMRs) in particular. Overall EMR adoption is finally taking off, but just as quickly we are hearing distressing reports of the growing number of failed implementations and practices removing “useless” systems. I would readily argue that any practice who has failed with an EMR has failed with their deployment execution. Any of the top 20 systems on the market are very good, and all have been implemented in at least several hundred medical practices (the larger vendors, in several thousand). Despite that every physician and every office thinks they are singly unique, they are not. A deployment failure is a commitment failure. And most frequently, the commitment failing is a practice or a physician’s decision not to pay for good help. A good integrated EMR and practice management system (PMS) exists in the small office for one reason – to reduce office overhead. It is a tool that helps you accomplish more with less. I would readily argue that any practice who has failed with an EMR has failed with their deployment execution.
  • 8. w w w . h i t b c c . c o m8 Offices that have been in practice for a number of years will spend the money on an EMR, and because of loyalty to their staff, will not eliminate positions. Again, I understand the loyalty, but please do not turn around and complain that you are not getting the return on your investment. Almost as annoying is to hear physicians talking about how electronic medical records should improve patient care, or the patient experience – with complete obliviousness to the business implications. Do not buy an EMR to yet further improve the quality of the widgets you are selling—this makes no sense, economically. Worse, it leads to the idiotic conclusion that payers or hospitals or employers should pay for your EMR. Good luck with that. The fact is that EMRs do much to improve healthcare quality, but that is an added benefit, and in today’s environment, not a reason to buy one. First and foremost, they allow you to do more with less…Less people, which is the best thing you can do to decrease the cost of a widget. To give you an example, I submit most claims on the same day patients are seen, though from time to time, I have to ask the providers to finish an outstanding note. As part of the note, each physician is responsible for their own coding. Again, no extra personnel dedicated to roles handled by our system. In addition to the administrative edits, eClinicalWorks now offers access to CodeCorrect’s knowledge base (a company focused on automating the overwhelming ICD-9, CPT, and HCPCS changes along with government and private payer rules related to them). I had petitioned eClinicalWorks for 2 years to incorporate CodeCorrect’s edits and am glad they finally did as I find it invaluable. It takes me about 15 minutes a day to submit all of our charges (approximately 40-60 claims). Each claim goes through the following process before it reaches the payer: coded by physician, checked for administrative errors by eCW, checked for potential coding violations by CodeCorrect, reviewed and edited by me if necessary and sent to our clearinghouse, Emdeon (formerly WebMD Envoy); the clearinghouse performs an additional edit before submitting to the payer. If the clearinghouse detects any errors, it will send a message to the office within a few hours so the claim can be corrected and resubmitted before it is sent to the payer, thus reducing a lengthy denial cycle. Do not buy an EMR to yet further improve the quality of the widgets you are selling — this makes no sense, economically.
  • 9. Copyright © 2008 bcc: Consulting. All Rights Reserved. 9 Practicing to Win The amazing efficiency of this process ensures claims are submitted promptly and accurately, minimizing later follow up. It’s a great concept: if you do it correctly the first time, you don’t have to have a dedicated staff to follow up on denials. The corollary to this is that when we do have denials, I can make the decision to follow up or not. It’s a crazy notion, but not all denials are worth following up on. I have no doubt that many other practices are better chasing down every cent, but our goal is to optimize our resources and return on investment. Less Space Rent or mortgage payments are likely any given practice’s second largest regularly recurring cost item. In theory, as is true with leasing vs. buying cars, there really shouldn’t be a financial difference between renting vs. owning. Of course, as with all things, short-term inefficiencies abound. Additionally, there are subtle trade-offs between owning and renting that generally come with implicit price tags. For instance, renting offers the added flexibility of moving later if you need additional space to grow into. Therefore, you may be willing to pay more for the “option” that renting offers. For simplicity’s sake, let’s just assume that it’s a zero sum gain, monthly rent vs. monthly mortgage. Let’s assume that you have a fixed amount of space for which you pay a fixed monthly amount. Are you fully utilizing that space? Are you maximizing your office’s ability to generate revenue? I was recently informed that the average physician should have about 1,500 sq. ft. So, in other words, a 3 physician practice should be about 4,500 sq. ft. Don’t get me wrong, I love data, lots of it. I love doing analysis on data. But this underscores a problem that is so typical of practice management. It reminds me of the story I once heard from a McKinsey or BCG consultant who, in complete admiration of his boss, told the story of how she informed a client that “on average, every person has one testicle and one breast,” clearly admonishing the use of meaningless statistics. Our office that originally supported a solo physician can now support 3 FTE physicians. We occupy a whopping 2,000 sq. ft. – that’s less than 700 sq. ft. per provider. Furthermore, we have ample space. I give my wife full credit for the office design. She is inherently a utilitarian and designed 6 exam rooms around a central work area. The back office that used to belong to just me, is now shared by the 3 physicians and me. The truth is that the physicians do not need an office, or at least an office in the traditional sense. If anything, an office gives one an opportunity to accumulate junk and personal odds and ends that are not even good enough to be kept at home. If the providers are seeing patients – in the exam rooms – they really do not need an office to hang out in. A chair, a It’s a crazy notion, but not all denials are worth following up on.
  • 10. w w w . h i t b c c . c o m10 desk, a computer to document ongoing encounters… not much else. In fact, while the 4 of us share a single office, you will rarely find more than 2 people in the office at any given time. I suspect the average occupancy is about 1.3. Of course, we do not have hundreds of square feet dedicated to paper charts. We also do not transcribe notes. I know that most EMRs support transcription – no doubt an early concession to those physicians who refused to change their ways – but it flies in the face of EMRs and adds a completely unnecessary cost. Perhaps one of the reasons that the office accommodates the four of us so easily is that I actually spend very little time in the office at all. I perform most of my management responsibilities from home or on the road via VPN (virtual private network) access. Additionally, each of our physicians has remote access to the server from home. If anyone is at the office after 5:15pm, it is because they choose to finish their notes in the quiet of the office. Greater Productivity Thus far, we have reduced the cost of our widget by minimizing support staff and maximizing the production capacity of our factory. There are a number of other things that we can do to minimize additional cost elements, but rather than address them individually, I would prefer to address them as one group under the heading — When to Spend vs. When to Skimp. In general, both my wife and I are big believers in sweat equity – a roll- up the sleeves, can-do attitude that can save money at just about every turn. For example, we purchased the majority of our office equipment, including exam tables, exam lights, a baby scale, and an autoclave, among other items, from a defunct medical practice in town. We bought most of our office furniture from an unfinished wood furniture store, that we subsequently finished ourselves. Trust me, there was real sweat involved in this. But knowing when to roll up the sleeves, and when to take out the check book is imperative. In fact, I lump so many different cost items into this header because it is probably the one area where most practices make their biggest mistake. When we built-out our office, I paid the builders to pull Cat 5 cable through our space, but I did all the technical work to punch down the cable and ultimately build out our entire network – the heart and soul of our operation. As soon as I was finished putting the whole thing together, I immediately contracted with an excellent network support group, UnlimitedPlus, to manage my network, specifically to provide continuous monitoring and disaster recovery services. Why? Because I am not an Knowing when to roll up the sleeves, and when to take out the check book is imperative.
  • 11. Copyright © 2008 bcc: Consulting. All Rights Reserved. 11 Practicing to Win expert network administrator. Furthermore, it took me 2 weeks, with help, to get the network up and running. If it fails, I want it up and running within 6 hours. This means having contingency servers, client PCs, network switches, and routers on hand, and the ability to recreate my network environment. I am proud of myself for putting the network together in the first place. I am much smarter and more effective in troubleshooting and solving problems on my own as a result; however, I recognize when to call in the experts. For not a whole lot more than we spend on our cleaning service, we have remote data back-up and a solid contingency plan in place. What’s more, I sleep comfortably each night knowing that if anything goes wrong with either our system or our network, we will have it all up and running within a day. Many practices are reluctant to pay for this type or level of service. Another common problem I’ve already alluded to, and one that I speak about often, is EMR/PMS vendor selection. When it comes to selecting an EMR and practice management system (PMS), offices seem to think that as long as they choose “the right” vendor, all of their problems will be solved. In truth, any of the top vendors’ systems are adequate, some better than others, and some much more expensive. The success or failure of an EMR/ PMS implementation has much more to do with the office’s network (IT infrastructure) and its staff’s willingness and ability to adapt to change (change management). Do not expect that simply choosing a vendor will ensure success. It won’t. Every decision involving resource utilization – chiefly physician and staff time – must be weighed against its opportunity cost. In other words, how else might that resource be deployed, or what else might that person be doing? Physicians are often referred to as bad business people. While somewhat deserved, the reputation really comes from the fact that very few physicians are formally schooled in business, and many physicians have type-A personalities. They are generally intelligent, self-reliant, and confident. These are great characteristics, but do not lend well to taking advice. Even worse, they seem to imbue many physicians with the intellectual curiosity and problem-solving to want to personally undertake unnecessary challenges. Interestingly enough, this self-sufficiency does not generally spill over into menial tasks like cleaning the office, or trade- specific specialties like accounting or law. Business acumen, strategic planning, management and to a large extent computers and computer networking, on the other hand, are all egalitarian undertakings that require no formal license or degree to practice. As a result, those with proven academic success and intelligence are wont to engage in them with surety and confidence. The cost of such erroneous misjudgment is twofold: first, subpar business performance, and second, either lost or interrupted time with patients, which hampers revenue- generation. Every decision involving resource utilization — chiefly physician and staff time — must be weighed against its opportunity cost.
  • 12. w w w . h i t b c c . c o m12 Know when to roll-up the sleeves and when to pay for good help, and apply frequently in all business undertakings. Greater Throughput In maximizing the capacity of our office (which effectively lowers our per- unit cost by increasing output without increasing fixed costs), we create an environment that allows us to sell additional widgets. In other words, our factory can now support greater throughput, but we still need to develop the customer base or demand to offset this new supply. Many practices, particularly well-established practices, have a surplus of demand and can accommodate the new supply quite readily. Others need to be a bit more aggressive and proactive in soliciting new patients. There are a number of effective, low-cost ways to do this. Again, one of the main objections to tasteful marketing is cost. Why spend money soliciting new patients when you will eventually stop accepting them? There is a very good reason for doing so. Again, think of your office as a factory. You are spending X dollars a month to run the factory, of which the vast majority of your costs are fixed Why spend money soliciting new patients when you will eventually stop accepting them? TC TRTC TRTC TT A A firm’s total cost (TC) curve typi- cally resembles a classic s-curve. Total costs quickly rise with each incremen- tal unit of output, reflecting an initial outlay of fixed costs. As the costs amortize over a higher quantity of output, the marginal cost (or cost for each additional unit) – or the slope of the TC curve – decreases until it nearly plateaus. Eventually the firm’s ability to generate additional units increasingly depends on higher vari- able costs, causing the curve to slope steeply upwards. B As a price taker, the competitive firm’s total revenue (TR) increases along a diagonal line, the marginal revenue is a constant slope. C Total Profit is simply total rev- enue minus total cost. This can be expressed as TR – TC = TT (profit). The maximum profit occurs at q* where the distance between the two curves is greatest.
  • 13. Copyright © 2008 bcc: Consulting. All Rights Reserved. 13 Practicing to Win and not variable. This creates what is known as “stickiness.” In other words, you may be able to scale back blocks of cost to cut back the output capacity of your factory. But you probably can do this at only certain points along your supply curve. For instance, you may only be able to spend .8X to run the factory at 80%, or .5X to run it at 50%. However, your overhead is not perfectly variable like the fine tuning volume knob on your stereo. This means that you are most likely paying X dollars to support 100% capacity, even if your throughput is only 85%. Analysis of the situation might reveal that you should actually lower your capacity to 80% so that you can align your cost structure with your utilization – it may be better to spend .8X for 80% than X for 85%. The opposite is also true. If you are spending X, but running at 85%, you should work to increase your capacity to 100%; but how hard? It depends. How much are you losing by not running at 100%? You may currently be profitable, but the inefficiency is undoubtedly costing you. The value of the ongoing loss will give you a much better understanding of the need to accelerate supply optimization. For example, how much should you be willing to spend on a 6 month marketing campaign that will reduce your under utilization from 12 months to 6? A By comparison, if we assume that all of our costs are fixed, we can clearly see that our total cost (TC) curve looks like a staircase – a fixed level of cost supports a specific level of output, beyond which point, the marginal cost is the entire cost of the next level of fixed costs. B Again, as a price-taker, our total revenue (TR) curve resembles the typical competitive firm. C Unlike the typical competitive firm, which has a single point of maximum profitability, we have multiple points. This clearly shows the importance of “right-sizing” your clinical operation to match patient load. TC TRTC TRTC TT1 TT2 TT3 q1 q2 q3
  • 14. w w w . h i t b c c . c o m14 Realizing that the concept of stickiness can be confusing, let me explain this further using a hypothetical medical practice example. Let’s assume that we have a 5,000 sq. ft. office with the following parameters: Rent 5,000 square feet ($10,000 a month) + 4 FTE Providers ($10,000 a month per provider) + 4 MAs ($2,500 per month per MA) + 3 Front-Office ($2,000 per month each) + 1 Back-Office ($3,000 per month) + 1 Office Manager ($6,000 per month) = Total Fixed Cost $75,000 per month = Total Capacity 100 patients per day = Average collection per patient encounter $90 What should we do, if anything, to run more optimally if we are only seeing 85 patients a day? First off, let’s calculate the value of our underutilization: 100 patient capacity - 85 patients per day (current level) = 15 patients per day 15 patients per day x $90/encounter = $1,350 per day x 21 work days per month = $28,350 month That’s a lot of money, but keep in mind we are a full 15% underutilized.
  • 15. Copyright © 2008 bcc: Consulting. All Rights Reserved. 15 Practicing to Win People, as with most fixed costs, are fixed in the short-term but variable in the long. In other words, if we know that we are going to be running at 85% of capacity for the foreseeable future, we can restructure our staffing to reduce costs and capacity. However, if the shortfall is only temporary, it is much more difficult to lay people off and rehire them only when they are needed (also called furloughing). Factoring in the costs of finding, hiring and training personnel, you can see why they are regarded as a fixed cost in the short-term. In our example, if we assume each physician has the exact same level of productivity, reducing our provider staff from 4 to 3 would immediately reduce our capacity by 25%. We would then be able to reduce some of the support staff and our overall fixed monthly costs. The net effect may actually be better than our starting point, but let’s assume we are growing, and our goal is not to downsize. A better alternative is to build-in some variability within our staffing. So, rather than having 4 providers who must maintain full-time positions, it is preferable to have at least one or two providers who have the flexibility to work a part-to-full time schedule. This gives us the ability to ratchet down our supply to better reflect demand. The same is true of our medical assistants (MAs). So, instead of having 4 full-time MAs, we may prefer to have 3 full time and 2 part-time. The part-time employees, in addition to giving us greater work-hour flexibility, simultaneously reduce our overall benefits burden. Basic Economic Theory According to Wikipedia, “microeconomics is a branch of economics that studies how individuals, households, and firms make decisions to allocate limited resources, typically in markets where goods or services are being bought and sold. Microeconomics examines how these decisions and behaviors affect the supply and demand for goods and services, which determines prices; and how prices, in turn, determine the supply and demand of goods and services.” In general “micro,” is extremely intuitive and explains so much about how and why people do what they do. I believe that if every physician were trained on just two simple microeconomic concepts they would be much better business people –the first, which I have already touched upon, is opportunity cost and the second is sunk cost. Opportunity cost is simply the cost or value that would be realized if the resources required for the contemplated undertaking were otherwise deployed. In other words, say a physician spends 30 minutes trying to configure a network printer. Had he opted instead to see 2 patients, he could have potentially billed $500 in charges, and collected $300. His opportunity cost is $300. Rather than trying to fix the printer himself, he could have hired a professional to fix the printer for $50. So, while the physician probably felt he was saving $50, he really lost $250. As its name suggests, opportunity cost assumes an “opportunity.” The physician’s time cannot generically be expressed as $300 per 30 minutes or $600 an hour. Such reasoning would prevent our physician from doing anything but seeing patients. Just because the physician has 30 minute periods where he can earn $300, does not mean that every 30 minutes of his time is worth $300. If, for instance, he had no other patients to see at 5:30pm, it may be more advantageous to take out the garbage and sweep and mop the office floors if the only other alternative were to sit and do nothing. (Though, sitting and doing nothing, in turn, has its own value that is harder to compute and may ultimately be more valuable than the $20 of cleaning services saved.) continued on page 16
  • 16. w w w . h i t b c c . c o m16 Structuring our staff in this manner will not increase our supply, but it will lower our monthly costs by smoothing our cost curve. For example, assume we can reduce both physician and MA staffing levels to 90%. This reduces physician salaries by $4,000 per month and MA salary by another $1,000. So, while we still have excess capacity, we have reduced our fixed costs by $5,000 (not including any potential benefits reductions). If instead, we decided to actively market for additional patients, how much should we be willing to spend? Using our previous assumptions that our shortfall would naturally be filled over the course of a year (through word of mouth, insurance directories, etc…), the value of the loss would equal: The point is that opportunity cost is dynamic and requires continuous reevaluation. Activities that during one interval may have a negative value can in another prove positive. Sunk costs, on the other hand, are non-recoverable costs. A commonly used example is that of a non-refundable movie ticket. If a person buys a non-refundable ticket and decides at some point during the movie that she is not enjoying it, she should only consider her opportunity cost and not the sunk cost of the movie ticket. In other words, the $7.50 for the ticket is gone. If she had the opportunity to do something else that would be preferable to sitting through a bad movie, she should do it. To do otherwise because of a mistaken belief that leaving early would somehow be “losing” the $7.50 is known as the sunk cost fallacy. The money was gone at the moment the ticket was purchased, and should not be a factor in any future decision. As applied to medical practice management, a common example of the sunk cost fallacy is a practice’s decision to keep “plugging-away” on the same old computer system that it has been using for the last 10 years (most likely a legacy practice management system). The argument that it has already been paid for has zero implications in calculating net present value (NPV) – the fundamental benchmark for any decision. By definition, “NPV is a standard method for the financial appraisal of long-term projects. Used for capital budgeting, and widely throughout economics, it measures the excess or shortfall of cash flows, in present value terms, once financing charges are met.” ALL decisions should involve an NPV calculation, whether formal or informal. Those with a positive value should be undertaken, and those with a negative value should not. At no point in an NPV calculation should you consider previous, unrecoverable, or sunk, costs. In fact, if you spent $10,000 on a system as recently as yesterday (and for simplicity’s sake assume TRTC a By building a degree of variability into our staffing, we can smooth our total cost (TC) curve as shown. The net effect is smaller negative profit- ability (area a) and greater positive profitability (area b). continued on page 17
  • 17. Copyright © 2008 bcc: Consulting. All Rights Reserved. 17 Practicing to Win $28,350 per month x 12 months = $340,200 ÷ 2 (assuming patient growth is equally distributed over 12 months) = $170,100 By comparison, if we were able to reduce the shortfall from 12 to 6 months, our loss would equal only: $28,350 per month x 6 months = $170,100 ÷ 2 (assuming patient growth is equally distributed over 6 months) = $85,050 This suggests that if we are able to run a marketing campaign that would reduce the period of our patient shortfall from 12 to 6 months, we would earn an additional $85,050. To put this there are no recurring costs associated with supporting the system), and find a different system today that costs say, $50,000, but offers a positive NPV, then you should purchase it. The system you purchased yesterday has no bearing on today’s decision. In other words, you cannot make-up for a previous poor decision by “sticking it out.” The result of such thinking is a multiplication of the number and effect of your poor decisions. These economic concepts extend well beyond easily calculable monetary decisions. For example, I would argue that the primary reason there is so much resistance to change is the sunk cost fallacy. When presented with a new system, policy, or procedure, people resist change. While people can be pig-headed, or “irrational” as an economist would say, they generally are not. The rash of failures and challenges associated with system change is not caused by rampant irrationality, or incompetence. Something else is at play. Whether the front-office receptionist, the office manager, or even the physician, each person learned to do their job a certain way. They invested time and energy, and likely feel they are proficient at accomplishing their responsibilities, regardless of whether true or not. The point is that they believe they are good at what they do. (Consider, for example, that research has consistently found that 9 out of 10 people believe they are smarter than the average person.) When confronted with change, the near-universal reaction is that the effort of learning something new does not justify the cost. The problem is that the person making the decision typically overvalues their current efficiency, undervalues the potential gains to be realized by changing (thus, resulting in an understated NPV), and finally cannot let go of the original effort required to learn their job in the first place (sunk cost fallacy). Nearly every decision in medical practice management involves these concepts and having a better understanding of their implications can greatly simplify and improve decision-making. continued on page 18
  • 18. w w w . h i t b c c . c o m18 into perspective, an aggressive marketing campaign might cost $5,000 to $10,000. So, to earn $85,000 at a cost of even $10,000 nets an additional $75,000 of income. Finally, with some basic principles in place, we can graphically display the effect productivity enhancing tools and processes have on our cost curve and ultimately profitability: The Top-Line Up to this point, we have focused on the lower half of the factory’s income statement, or the expenses. Working in the perfectly competitive commodity business of widgets, our ability to improve our performance is primarily limited to the realm of cost and productivity management. Remember, we are not setting the price of our goods, the market is. After all the work we have discussed to run our factory as efficiently as possible, what do you think the net difference is between the best and worst performing practices? I would bet that, adjusting for outliers and normalizing for comparison, the best practices earn 10% higher income as a result of good practice management. 10% is substantial, particularly if it all flows through to the bottom line. Now, let’s relax our assumption that the market fixes the price of widgets. It still does, but instead of a single price, let’s assume it fixes the price for widgets at 3 distinct levels: 1 small independent practice, 2 moderate group affiliated practice, and 3 large affiliated practice. Small independent practices as the label describes are independent (not group or hospital owned) and are typically comprised of 5 or fewer physicians. Roughly 75% of all physicians practice in these groups. Moderate group affiliated practices are either: a) larger group practices, b) belong to a larger parent organization, or c) affiliate with enough practices to form an association, such as an independent physician association (IPA). Moderate group affiliated practices typically include anywhere from 50 to The enhanced productivity provided by an effective EMR/PMS increases initial total cost (TC1 vs. TC0), but ex- tends the reach of fixed cost tranches – essentially, you can do more with less. This graph is conceptual only and not drawn to scale. The net effect is greater total profitability (areas under the TR curve) for TC1 vs. TC0. TC0 TC1 TR
  • 19. Copyright © 2008 bcc: Consulting. All Rights Reserved. 19 Practicing to Win several -hundred physicians, or more. A small independent practice can gain leverage by joining such an association, as my wife’s practice has done. Finally, the large affiliated practice is either part of a large hospital or group affiliation that may have many thousands of physicians. What do you think the market pays for widgets across these 3 groups? Keep in mind that fee schedules are confidential, so not readily comparable. When the small independent practice “opts-in” to a payer’s contract, they are given the most basic and lopsided fee schedule possible. Let’s just call this Y per widget (our baseline). With the added leverage of a moderate group affiliation the exact same practice would likely see their fee schedule jump to somewhere between 1.15Y to 1.20Y – a 15%-20% increase. The large affiliated practice, in turn, would likely see fee schedules in the neighborhood of 1.2Y to 1.4Y – a 20% to 40% increase over the baseline! Again, these different fee schedules have zero correlation to quality. It should be very clear that while it is important to run a good practice – a 10% differential is enormous ($100,000 to the bottom line for every $1,000,000 of gross revenue) – it is more critical to get on the right contracts. This should help explain to the casual observer how some apparently well run practices have difficulty staying afloat, while other clearly inefficient operations seem to thrive. Keep in mind that this situation is not sustainable. Eventually, the market will correct itself and those providing good, quality care will be justly rewarded, and better so if they can also run a good business operation. In the interim, practices must understand the dynamics of the current environment if they are to succeed. If the same firm, with the same cost curve, were offered three different fee schedules (total revenue curves), the impact to total profitability is represented by TT0 , TT1 , and TT2 . TR0 TR1 TR2 TC TT0 TT1 TT2
  • 20. w w w . h i t b c c . c o m20 Future Challenges Regardless of the appropriateness of the moniker “Consumer-Driven Healthcare,” the shift of ultimate financial responsibility from employers to employees, or healthcare consumers, brings with it both good and bad. For one, quality cannot be driven by payers. There are far too many variables and unknowns to effectively benchmark clinical outcomes. Worse yet, allowing the payers to define the quality criteria and metrics is a bit like having the foxes establish security protocols at the hen houses. Payers are far more interested in and incentivized to maximize profitability than improve clinical outcomes. Don’t let the fact that the two occasionally intersect lead you to conclude otherwise. As in all industries, the consumers of goods or services should be the ones to determine the value of that which they seek. To assume that a third party is better equipped to measure the quality of care provided than the patient receiving the care is beyond paternalistic, and has consistently proven inaccurate. I am much better equipped, for instance, to determine the quality provided by my physician than my auto mechanic. But other than industry self-regulation, which healthcare does as well, no outside organization intervenes directly on my behalf to protect me from making a bad auto repair decision or from being taken advantage of. Ultimately, as patients become more empowered to spend their own dollars on healthcare, the tried and true laws of supply and demand will kick in. Good physicians will be highly sought after. Lesser physicians will be in less demand, and the market will adjust prices accordingly. The platforms for consumers sharing their experiences and feedback have grown exponentially over the last few years and will likely continue as patients assume more of their responsibilities as consumers. A short-term problem with the newer healthcare financing model is that more reimbursement is coming directly from the patient.   When you consider that your worst payer is almost certainly your patients themselves (consumer spending reports generally show that consumers place medical bills somewhere between Ho-Hos and Ding-Dongs on their priority list of debt repayment), practices must become more aggressive in verifying benefit eligibility and collecting payment in advance of service. As in all industries, the consumers of goods or services should be the ones to determine the value of that which they seek.
  • 21. Copyright © 2008 bcc: Consulting. All Rights Reserved. 21 Practicing to Win Final Thoughts Again, my rationale for comparing the physician office to a factory is in no way intended to detract from the great care and sacrifice so many countless physicians make day in and day out. To the contrary, I feel that our healthcare system should reward those commensurate to the service they provide, rather than arbitrarily, or even worse, politically. Healthcare has historically fallen into a special class of industry and business that even in the eyes of the staunchest laissez-faire economists has deservedly required government intervention and oversight. The argument has long been based on the notion of information asymmetry – the physician or provider has a disproportionate knowledge or access to information than the consumer. Thus, in protecting the rights of the consumer, the government is justified in intervening to ensure a level playing field. It’s a reasonable concept, but in practice, does not work. The government is largely responsible for the dysfunctional system that we have today. Rather than embarking on a tirade of Medicare and Medicaid, I prefer to focus on those things that physicians and practices can do to not only survive, but thrive. Sound economic and financial practices can greatly improve any medical practice, even in today’s managed care environment. As healthcare shifts to a more traditional free-market system, understanding of economic theory and principles will become even more pertinent and crucial. The continued transformation of healthcare over the next decade promises yet more chaos; but rather than throwing your hands up in resignation, ponder Albert Einstein’s wisdom and appreciate the boundless opportunity before us.
  • 22. Unlimited Plus is North Carolina’s premier Healthcare IT Services Provider, specializing in network management, EMR/PMS implementation and infor- mation technology consulting services. With hundreds of machines under management across healthcare organizations large and small, Unlimited Plus consistently delivers high-quality and responsive technical support. To learn more, visit us at http://www.unlimitedplus.com/Healthcare, or call (888) 865-7587.