SlideShare a Scribd company logo
1 of 12
Estimation of Profit-Maximizing Price for One Round of Golf
Econ 382
Ellis, Greg
Alexander F. Woodhouse, Shiqiu Wu, Qiong Hu
Executive Summary:
In this project, we are given data from 22 golf courses in the greater Seattle area. We
want to find the demand function for golf courses in terms of the price, given all of the
other explanatory variables. Our goal is to find the best estimation of the demand function
for the MGS courses given the sample provided. In addition to giving advice to MGS as to
whether or not they should implement the seasonal green fee, we also want to find out if
they should fund the paving of cart paths or the building of driving ranges first, with the
interest of increasing their revenue.
First, we make our educated guess for the relationship of each variable on ROUNDS.
Then we analyze the unrestricted model by looking at p-values. Since WINTER*FEE, YARD
and RANGE have insignificant p-values, we use Wald Test to confirm that they are
irrelevant variables and remove them. When we get the improved model, we use White
Test to detect the Heteroskedasticity and adjust our current model for it. By now, each
variable has a small p-value and the adjusted R square increases. Then we analyzed the
sign and magnitude of each variable and found they are all reasonable and logical. Finally,
we conclude this model is best linear unbiased estimates. To give our formal analysis to the
MGS courses, we computed and compared price elasticity of demand in winter time and in
non-winter time, and concluded that MGS should use seasonal green fees since P.E.D. in
winter is more elastic than in non-winter time. Also, we suggest that MGS should build cart
paths through all three of their courses before building driving ranges.
Formal Analysis:
The nonprofit organization Municipal Golf of Seattle (MGS) currently manages three
golf courses owned by the city of Seattle: Jackson, Jefferson, and West Seattle. As their
economic advisers, we have been hired to advise them if, as well as how much, they should
reduce their greens fees during the winter months, as well as helping them decide where to
allocate additional funds for capital improvements. Because MGS works with the city of
Seattle and all costs are handled by the state, our entire analysis will be under the
assumption that total costs are zero, and therefore total profit is equal to total revenue. It
follows that in determining how we will advise MGS, our goal will be to maximize the total
revenue, subject to a number of constraints.
To help us answer these two questions, we have been given access to data from 22
golf courses in the greater Seattle area, measured once a month over a one-year span. For
each of these 268 data points, the total number of times the course was played during the
given month at the given course (ROUNDS) is given, along with a number of possible
explanatory variables corresponding to the data point in question. To investigate the roles
of these possible explanatory variables on the dependent variable ROUNDS, we first made
an educated guess about their relationship with ROUNDS as follows:
𝑅𝑂𝑈𝑁𝐷𝑆 = 𝑓( 𝐹𝐸𝐸, 𝐹𝐸𝐸𝑆𝑈𝐵, 𝑅𝐴𝐼𝑁, 𝑇𝐸𝑀𝑃, 𝑅𝐴𝑇𝐼𝑁𝐺, 𝑆𝐿𝑂𝑃𝐸, 𝑌𝐴𝑅𝐷, 𝐷𝐼𝑆, 𝐶𝐴𝑅𝑇, 𝑅𝐴𝑁𝐺𝐸, 𝑊𝐼𝑁𝑇𝐸𝑅, 𝑀𝐺𝑆)
( −, +, −, +, +, −, ?, −, +, ?, −, ? )
In our attempt to maximize the total revenue, it will be represented by the product:
𝑅𝑂𝑈𝑁𝐷𝑆 ∗ 𝐹𝐸𝐸, subject to the constraints of the values of the other relevant explanatory
variables present. For the first question, we will examine the elasticity of demand at the
MGS courses in the winter and non-winter, and if applicable, find the value of FEE that
maximizes total revenue during winter. But before we can determine either of these things,
we need to use the data to estimate the best possible model for the demand of ROUNDS.
Among the possible explanatory variables listed above is FEE, which is the average
price charged by the given course for each round of golf played in a given month. We expect
that FEE would have a negative relationship with ROUNDS, which corresponds to the law of
demand in economic theory. To determine the degree and magnitude of this relationship,
we need to develop a model that includes the effects of the other relevant variables as well.
If we can verify that certain assumptions have been met, then we can use the ordinary least
squares (OLS) method and know that it will provide the best linear unbiased estimates of
this relationship.
An unrestricted model (Figure 1) is available as a potential estimation model,
however, it is doubtful that it is the best fit. Specifically, we suspect that there could be at
least one irrelevant variable in the model. Running t-Tests with the null hypothesis
𝐻0: 𝛽 𝑘 = 0 against the alternative hypothesis 𝐻 𝑎: 𝛽 𝑘 ≠ 0 for each of the independent
variables ( 𝑘 = 1, 2,… , 17), we see that there is very high probability that the null
hypothesis cannot be rejected for the coefficients of YARD, RANGE, and WINTER*FEE. To
test if these three variables can be removed from the model, we run a Wald (F) Test with
the null hypothesis 𝐻0: 𝛽 𝑌𝐴𝑅𝐷 = 𝛽 𝑅𝐴𝑁𝐺𝐸 = 𝛽 𝑊𝐼𝑁𝑇𝐸𝑅 ∗𝐹𝐸𝐸 = 0 against the alternative
hypothesis 𝐻𝐴: 𝑎𝑡 𝑙𝑒𝑎𝑠𝑡 𝑜𝑛𝑒 𝑜𝑓 𝑡ℎ𝑒 𝛽𝑠 𝑖𝑠 𝑛𝑜𝑡 𝑒𝑞𝑢𝑎𝑙 𝑡𝑜 𝑧𝑒𝑟𝑜. We calculated that the
observed 𝐹𝑠𝑡𝑎𝑡 = 0.102417 < 𝐹3 ,246
∗ (0.05) = 2.60, and so we fail to reject the null
hypothesis (Figure 2). This means that we can improve the fit of our model by eliminating
these irrelevant variables, at the 5% level of significance.
After we eliminated those irrelevant variables, we get a restricted model without
irrelevant variables (WINTER*FEE, YARD, and RANGE) (Figure 3). Now we want to
determine whether or not there is heteroskedasticity in our model. If there is, then we must
eliminate it if we want to be certain that we are attaining the best linear unbiased
estimates. To test for heteroskedasticity in our model, we used the White test, primarily
because it has the ability to test for a wider range of forms of heteroskedasticity, making it
more comprehensive and precise than the Park test. We performed the White test with the
null hypothesis 𝐻0: 𝛼1 = 𝛼2 = ⋯ = 𝛼90 = 0 against the alternative hypothesis
𝐻 𝑎: 𝑎𝑡 𝑙𝑒𝑎𝑠𝑡 𝑜𝑛𝑒 𝑜𝑓 𝑡ℎ𝑒 𝛼 𝑣𝑎𝑙𝑢𝑒𝑠 𝑖𝑠 𝑛𝑜𝑡 𝑒𝑞𝑢𝑎𝑙 𝑡𝑜 𝑧𝑒𝑟𝑜, and we obtain a statistic equal to
𝑜𝑏𝑠 ∗ 𝑅2
= 268 ∗ 𝑅2
= 131.2916, which is larger than the critical value which is
𝜒90
2 (0.05) = 113.145. This result means that we must reject the White Test at a significance
level of 5%, which leads us to conclude that there is heteroskedasticity in our current
model. To fix the heteroskedasticity, we must adjust the Standard Errors of each errorterm
to account for it. It shows the Standard Errors for coefficients decreased after our
adjustment (Figure 5).
Now that we have adjusted our model for heteroskedasticity, we can be confident
that we have found a model for ROUNDS that has homoscedasticity. To be sure that this
model is realistic and logical, we must verify that the respective signs and magnitudes of
the coefficients for each characteristic match our initial intuition. The first thing we notice
is that the coefficient for FEE is positive, which contradicts both our intuition and the law of
demand. For the purposes of our analysis, we are only concerned with the demand model
pertaining to the MGS courses. In terms of our analysis, this means that we only care about
the condition of the model in which 𝑚𝑔𝑠 = 1. Under this condition, the total effect of FEE
on ROUNDS is always negative because the coefficient corresponding to MGS*FEE (which is
calculated to be -337.5988) offsets the positive effect of FEE on ROUNDS ( 𝛽 𝐹𝐸𝐸 +
𝛽 𝐹𝐸𝐸∗𝑀𝐺𝑆 < 0) . The coefficient of FEESUB is consistent with our intuition, and shows a
positive relationship between the fee charged by other courses and the demand for a
specific course. This is also in correspondence the effect of the price of a substitute on
demand in economic theory. The coefficient of RATING is also positive, which matches our
intuition, which was that the courses with higher ratings in terms of difficulty would attract
better golfers, but not necessarily detract golfers with less skill. On the other hand, the
negative coefficient in front of SLOPE matches our intuition because less skilled golfers
would prefer a course with less hills, but remain ambivalent about the rating. WINTER has
a negative relationship with ROUNDS, and the coefficient in front of WINTER has a very
large magnitude (𝛽 𝑊𝐼𝑁𝑇𝐸𝑅 =-1586.647), which matches our intuition as well because days
are shorter during the winter, and so there are less available tee times, in addition, the
weather conditions are not as favorable. We estimated that RAIN is a more important
factor than TEMP. RAIN has a bigger absolute coefficient value than TEMP has, which
makes sense because even the temperature was comfortable for golfing, people still would
be less likely to go golfing if it was rainy. With regards to the effects of TEMP, we would
expect positive correlation with ROUNDS because golf is generally more popular in areas
with warmer climates. Finally, the coefficients of CART*WINTER and DISTANCE interpret
that people would go to the golf course with cart path more, and have less preferences on
the courses which are further from Seattle. Besides, each variable has a small (significant) p
value, and the sign of each coefficient is reasonable and logical. Also, the adjusted R squared
value increased to 𝑅̅2
=0.865925 which is higher than 0.864380, the previous value it had
in the unrestricted model. Now that we have verified that the implications of our model
hold true in terms of logic and intuition, we can conclude that this model (figure 5)
provides the best linear unbiased estimates.
Based on this restricted model, we can provide some consulting advice to MGS
regarding the structure of their greens fees, specifically in the winter months. We
calculated the price elasticity of demand for MGS golf courses during winter and non-
winter time to determine if MGS should implement the seasonal rate. We calculated the
price elasticity of demand in wintertime (WINTER=1) to be 𝜂 = −2.220695 , and
𝜂 = −0.546797 as the price elasticity of demand during non-winter time (WINTER=0).
Since (-2.220695)<-1, it tells us that it is elastic during winter, which means a small change
in price causes a larger change in quantity. Also, the price elasticity of demand in winter is
more elastic than the one in non-winter time because |-2.220695|>|-0.546797|. According
to this result, we recommend MGS to use seasonal rates, specifically by lowering their
greens fees in the winter. Since 𝑇𝑜𝑡𝑎𝑙 𝑅𝑒𝑣𝑒𝑛𝑢𝑒 = 𝑇𝑅 = 𝑃 ∗ 𝑄 = 𝐹𝐸𝐸 ∗ 𝑅𝑂𝑈𝑁𝐷𝑆, if the
price elasticity of demand is elastic, we can increase the total revue by decreasing the value
of FEE. Specifically, MGS will maximize their revenue, and therefore their profits, by
lowering their winter-time greens fees to $12.20 (complete derivation in appendix B).
To consider whether to build the cart path or the driving range first, we go back to
look at the unrestricted model since it includes both CART*WINTER and RANGE. We found
CART*WINTER has much larger coefficient value than RANGE, so this means cart has larger
impact on increasing ROUNDS than driving range. Therefore, we suggest MGS to fund the
paving of cart paths first.
Appendix A
Figure 1 Unrestricted Model
Figure 2 Wald Test (F-test)
Figure 3 Restricted Model
Figure 4 White Test (Heteroskedasticity)
... (omission of extraneous data)…
Figure 5 Best Fit Model
Appendix B
Derivation of the Profit-Maximizing Fee during the Winter:
𝑁𝑂𝑇𝐸: 𝑡ℎ𝑟𝑜𝑢𝑔ℎ𝑜𝑢𝑡 𝑡ℎ𝑖𝑠 𝑑𝑒𝑟𝑖𝑣𝑎𝑡𝑖𝑜𝑛, 𝑎𝑠𝑠𝑢𝑚𝑒 𝐹𝐸𝐸 = 𝑝, 𝑎𝑛𝑑 𝑅𝑂𝑈𝑁𝐷𝑆( 𝐹𝐸𝐸) = 𝑞( 𝑝)
𝑃𝑟𝑜𝑓𝑖𝑡 = 𝜋( 𝑝) = 𝑇𝑅( 𝑝) − 𝑇𝐶 = 𝑇𝑅( 𝑝), 𝑠𝑖𝑛𝑐𝑒 𝑇𝐶 = 0
𝑇𝑜𝑡𝑎𝑙 𝑅𝑒𝑣𝑒𝑛𝑢𝑒 = 𝑇𝑅( 𝑝) = [ 𝑞( 𝑝)]∙ 𝑝
𝑞( 𝑝) = 𝛽0 − 𝛽1 𝑝 − 𝛽2 𝑝2
𝜋( 𝑝) = 𝑇𝑅( 𝑝) = [ 𝛽0 − 𝛽1 𝑝 − 𝛽2 𝑝2] ∙ 𝑝 = 𝛽0 𝑝 − 𝛽1 𝑝2
− 𝛽2 𝑝3
𝑚𝑎𝑥
{𝑝}
[ 𝜋( 𝑝)]:
𝜕
𝜕𝑝
[ 𝜋( 𝑝∗)] = 0,
𝜕2
𝜕𝑝2
[ 𝜋( 𝑝∗)] < 0
𝜕
𝜕𝑝
[ 𝜋( 𝑝)] = 𝛽0 − 2𝛽1 𝑝 − 3𝛽2 𝑝2
= 0
𝑝 =
−2𝛽1 ± √(2𝛽1)2 − 4(3𝛽2)(−𝛽0)
2(3𝛽2)
=
−𝛽1
(3𝛽2)
±
√(2𝛽1)2 − 4(3𝛽2)(−𝛽0)
2(3𝛽2)
𝜕2
𝜕𝑝2
[ 𝜋( 𝑝)] = −2𝛽1 − 6𝛽2 𝑝 < 0
𝑝∗
>
−𝛽1
(3𝛽2)
so:
𝑝∗
=
−𝛽1
(3𝛽2)
+
√(2𝛽1)2 − 4(3𝛽2)(−𝛽0)
2(3𝛽2)
by estimating 𝛽0, 𝛽1, 𝑎𝑛𝑑 𝛽2 with our regression coefficients (and average values of input
variables held constant) we find that:
𝑝∗
= $12.20

More Related Content

What's hot

Ib math studies internal assessment final draft
Ib math studies internal assessment final draftIb math studies internal assessment final draft
Ib math studies internal assessment final draft
Billy Egg
 

What's hot (18)

Regression analysis
Regression analysisRegression analysis
Regression analysis
 
B025209013
B025209013B025209013
B025209013
 
Correlation and regression
Correlation and regressionCorrelation and regression
Correlation and regression
 
Correlation and regression
Correlation and regressionCorrelation and regression
Correlation and regression
 
Correlation and regression
Correlation and regressionCorrelation and regression
Correlation and regression
 
Chapter 10
Chapter 10Chapter 10
Chapter 10
 
Simple linear regressionn and Correlation
Simple linear regressionn and CorrelationSimple linear regressionn and Correlation
Simple linear regressionn and Correlation
 
Regression analysis
Regression analysisRegression analysis
Regression analysis
 
Linear regression and correlation analysis ppt @ bec doms
Linear regression and correlation analysis ppt @ bec domsLinear regression and correlation analysis ppt @ bec doms
Linear regression and correlation analysis ppt @ bec doms
 
Simple (and Simplistic) Introduction to Econometrics and Linear Regression
Simple (and Simplistic) Introduction to Econometrics and Linear RegressionSimple (and Simplistic) Introduction to Econometrics and Linear Regression
Simple (and Simplistic) Introduction to Econometrics and Linear Regression
 
Ib math studies internal assessment final draft
Ib math studies internal assessment final draftIb math studies internal assessment final draft
Ib math studies internal assessment final draft
 
P G STAT 531 Lecture 9 Correlation
P G STAT 531 Lecture 9 CorrelationP G STAT 531 Lecture 9 Correlation
P G STAT 531 Lecture 9 Correlation
 
Final report mkt
Final report mktFinal report mkt
Final report mkt
 
Regression analysis
Regression analysisRegression analysis
Regression analysis
 
Correlation and regression impt
Correlation and regression imptCorrelation and regression impt
Correlation and regression impt
 
Regression Analysis
Regression AnalysisRegression Analysis
Regression Analysis
 
Regression
RegressionRegression
Regression
 
Correlation of height and shoe size
Correlation of height and shoe sizeCorrelation of height and shoe size
Correlation of height and shoe size
 

Viewers also liked (8)

Law of demand
Law of demandLaw of demand
Law of demand
 
Elasticity+and+its+application
Elasticity+and+its+applicationElasticity+and+its+application
Elasticity+and+its+application
 
Elasticity of demand
Elasticity of demandElasticity of demand
Elasticity of demand
 
Elasticity Of Demand
Elasticity Of DemandElasticity Of Demand
Elasticity Of Demand
 
Tutor2u - Price Elasticity of Demand
Tutor2u - Price Elasticity of DemandTutor2u - Price Elasticity of Demand
Tutor2u - Price Elasticity of Demand
 
Lease and ijarah
Lease and ijarahLease and ijarah
Lease and ijarah
 
Demand and supply
Demand and supplyDemand and supply
Demand and supply
 
Elasticity Of Supply And Demand
Elasticity Of Supply And DemandElasticity Of Supply And Demand
Elasticity Of Supply And Demand
 

Similar to Golf Final Project 4.0

Predicting US house prices using Multiple Linear Regression in R
Predicting US house prices using Multiple Linear Regression in RPredicting US house prices using Multiple Linear Regression in R
Predicting US house prices using Multiple Linear Regression in R
Sotiris Baratsas
 
Machine learning (13)
Machine learning (13)Machine learning (13)
Machine learning (13)
NYversity
 
Classification via Logistic Regression
Classification via Logistic RegressionClassification via Logistic Regression
Classification via Logistic Regression
Taweh Beysolow II
 
Application of Graphic LASSO in Portfolio Optimization_Yixuan Chen & Mengxi J...
Application of Graphic LASSO in Portfolio Optimization_Yixuan Chen & Mengxi J...Application of Graphic LASSO in Portfolio Optimization_Yixuan Chen & Mengxi J...
Application of Graphic LASSO in Portfolio Optimization_Yixuan Chen & Mengxi J...
Mengxi Jiang
 
FinalThesis_AnasRadouani
FinalThesis_AnasRadouaniFinalThesis_AnasRadouani
FinalThesis_AnasRadouani
Anas Raduani
 
The future is uncertain. Some events do have a very small probabil.docx
The future is uncertain. Some events do have a very small probabil.docxThe future is uncertain. Some events do have a very small probabil.docx
The future is uncertain. Some events do have a very small probabil.docx
oreo10
 

Similar to Golf Final Project 4.0 (20)

Ols by hiron
Ols by hironOls by hiron
Ols by hiron
 
Predicting US house prices using Multiple Linear Regression in R
Predicting US house prices using Multiple Linear Regression in RPredicting US house prices using Multiple Linear Regression in R
Predicting US house prices using Multiple Linear Regression in R
 
A PRACTICAL POWERFUL ROBUST AND INTERPRETABLE FAMILY OF CORRELATION COEFFICIE...
A PRACTICAL POWERFUL ROBUST AND INTERPRETABLE FAMILY OF CORRELATION COEFFICIE...A PRACTICAL POWERFUL ROBUST AND INTERPRETABLE FAMILY OF CORRELATION COEFFICIE...
A PRACTICAL POWERFUL ROBUST AND INTERPRETABLE FAMILY OF CORRELATION COEFFICIE...
 
Machine learning (13)
Machine learning (13)Machine learning (13)
Machine learning (13)
 
Classification via Logistic Regression
Classification via Logistic RegressionClassification via Logistic Regression
Classification via Logistic Regression
 
Multivariate time series
Multivariate time seriesMultivariate time series
Multivariate time series
 
Econometrics project
Econometrics projectEconometrics project
Econometrics project
 
Cs229 notes12
Cs229 notes12Cs229 notes12
Cs229 notes12
 
Line uo,please
Line uo,pleaseLine uo,please
Line uo,please
 
161783709 chapter-04-answers
161783709 chapter-04-answers161783709 chapter-04-answers
161783709 chapter-04-answers
 
161783709 chapter-04-answers
161783709 chapter-04-answers161783709 chapter-04-answers
161783709 chapter-04-answers
 
Correlation and regression
Correlation and regressionCorrelation and regression
Correlation and regression
 
Application of Graphic LASSO in Portfolio Optimization_Yixuan Chen & Mengxi J...
Application of Graphic LASSO in Portfolio Optimization_Yixuan Chen & Mengxi J...Application of Graphic LASSO in Portfolio Optimization_Yixuan Chen & Mengxi J...
Application of Graphic LASSO in Portfolio Optimization_Yixuan Chen & Mengxi J...
 
FinalThesis_AnasRadouani
FinalThesis_AnasRadouaniFinalThesis_AnasRadouani
FinalThesis_AnasRadouani
 
The future is uncertain. Some events do have a very small probabil.docx
The future is uncertain. Some events do have a very small probabil.docxThe future is uncertain. Some events do have a very small probabil.docx
The future is uncertain. Some events do have a very small probabil.docx
 
REG.pptx
REG.pptxREG.pptx
REG.pptx
 
Interpreting Regression Results - Machine Learning
Interpreting Regression Results - Machine LearningInterpreting Regression Results - Machine Learning
Interpreting Regression Results - Machine Learning
 
200994363
200994363200994363
200994363
 
Chapter III.pptx
Chapter III.pptxChapter III.pptx
Chapter III.pptx
 
Regression for class teaching
Regression for class teachingRegression for class teaching
Regression for class teaching
 

Golf Final Project 4.0

  • 1. Estimation of Profit-Maximizing Price for One Round of Golf Econ 382 Ellis, Greg Alexander F. Woodhouse, Shiqiu Wu, Qiong Hu Executive Summary: In this project, we are given data from 22 golf courses in the greater Seattle area. We want to find the demand function for golf courses in terms of the price, given all of the other explanatory variables. Our goal is to find the best estimation of the demand function for the MGS courses given the sample provided. In addition to giving advice to MGS as to whether or not they should implement the seasonal green fee, we also want to find out if they should fund the paving of cart paths or the building of driving ranges first, with the interest of increasing their revenue. First, we make our educated guess for the relationship of each variable on ROUNDS. Then we analyze the unrestricted model by looking at p-values. Since WINTER*FEE, YARD and RANGE have insignificant p-values, we use Wald Test to confirm that they are irrelevant variables and remove them. When we get the improved model, we use White Test to detect the Heteroskedasticity and adjust our current model for it. By now, each variable has a small p-value and the adjusted R square increases. Then we analyzed the sign and magnitude of each variable and found they are all reasonable and logical. Finally, we conclude this model is best linear unbiased estimates. To give our formal analysis to the MGS courses, we computed and compared price elasticity of demand in winter time and in non-winter time, and concluded that MGS should use seasonal green fees since P.E.D. in winter is more elastic than in non-winter time. Also, we suggest that MGS should build cart paths through all three of their courses before building driving ranges.
  • 2. Formal Analysis: The nonprofit organization Municipal Golf of Seattle (MGS) currently manages three golf courses owned by the city of Seattle: Jackson, Jefferson, and West Seattle. As their economic advisers, we have been hired to advise them if, as well as how much, they should reduce their greens fees during the winter months, as well as helping them decide where to allocate additional funds for capital improvements. Because MGS works with the city of Seattle and all costs are handled by the state, our entire analysis will be under the assumption that total costs are zero, and therefore total profit is equal to total revenue. It follows that in determining how we will advise MGS, our goal will be to maximize the total revenue, subject to a number of constraints. To help us answer these two questions, we have been given access to data from 22 golf courses in the greater Seattle area, measured once a month over a one-year span. For each of these 268 data points, the total number of times the course was played during the given month at the given course (ROUNDS) is given, along with a number of possible explanatory variables corresponding to the data point in question. To investigate the roles of these possible explanatory variables on the dependent variable ROUNDS, we first made an educated guess about their relationship with ROUNDS as follows: 𝑅𝑂𝑈𝑁𝐷𝑆 = 𝑓( 𝐹𝐸𝐸, 𝐹𝐸𝐸𝑆𝑈𝐵, 𝑅𝐴𝐼𝑁, 𝑇𝐸𝑀𝑃, 𝑅𝐴𝑇𝐼𝑁𝐺, 𝑆𝐿𝑂𝑃𝐸, 𝑌𝐴𝑅𝐷, 𝐷𝐼𝑆, 𝐶𝐴𝑅𝑇, 𝑅𝐴𝑁𝐺𝐸, 𝑊𝐼𝑁𝑇𝐸𝑅, 𝑀𝐺𝑆) ( −, +, −, +, +, −, ?, −, +, ?, −, ? ) In our attempt to maximize the total revenue, it will be represented by the product: 𝑅𝑂𝑈𝑁𝐷𝑆 ∗ 𝐹𝐸𝐸, subject to the constraints of the values of the other relevant explanatory variables present. For the first question, we will examine the elasticity of demand at the MGS courses in the winter and non-winter, and if applicable, find the value of FEE that
  • 3. maximizes total revenue during winter. But before we can determine either of these things, we need to use the data to estimate the best possible model for the demand of ROUNDS. Among the possible explanatory variables listed above is FEE, which is the average price charged by the given course for each round of golf played in a given month. We expect that FEE would have a negative relationship with ROUNDS, which corresponds to the law of demand in economic theory. To determine the degree and magnitude of this relationship, we need to develop a model that includes the effects of the other relevant variables as well. If we can verify that certain assumptions have been met, then we can use the ordinary least squares (OLS) method and know that it will provide the best linear unbiased estimates of this relationship. An unrestricted model (Figure 1) is available as a potential estimation model, however, it is doubtful that it is the best fit. Specifically, we suspect that there could be at least one irrelevant variable in the model. Running t-Tests with the null hypothesis 𝐻0: 𝛽 𝑘 = 0 against the alternative hypothesis 𝐻 𝑎: 𝛽 𝑘 ≠ 0 for each of the independent variables ( 𝑘 = 1, 2,… , 17), we see that there is very high probability that the null hypothesis cannot be rejected for the coefficients of YARD, RANGE, and WINTER*FEE. To test if these three variables can be removed from the model, we run a Wald (F) Test with the null hypothesis 𝐻0: 𝛽 𝑌𝐴𝑅𝐷 = 𝛽 𝑅𝐴𝑁𝐺𝐸 = 𝛽 𝑊𝐼𝑁𝑇𝐸𝑅 ∗𝐹𝐸𝐸 = 0 against the alternative hypothesis 𝐻𝐴: 𝑎𝑡 𝑙𝑒𝑎𝑠𝑡 𝑜𝑛𝑒 𝑜𝑓 𝑡ℎ𝑒 𝛽𝑠 𝑖𝑠 𝑛𝑜𝑡 𝑒𝑞𝑢𝑎𝑙 𝑡𝑜 𝑧𝑒𝑟𝑜. We calculated that the observed 𝐹𝑠𝑡𝑎𝑡 = 0.102417 < 𝐹3 ,246 ∗ (0.05) = 2.60, and so we fail to reject the null hypothesis (Figure 2). This means that we can improve the fit of our model by eliminating these irrelevant variables, at the 5% level of significance.
  • 4. After we eliminated those irrelevant variables, we get a restricted model without irrelevant variables (WINTER*FEE, YARD, and RANGE) (Figure 3). Now we want to determine whether or not there is heteroskedasticity in our model. If there is, then we must eliminate it if we want to be certain that we are attaining the best linear unbiased estimates. To test for heteroskedasticity in our model, we used the White test, primarily because it has the ability to test for a wider range of forms of heteroskedasticity, making it more comprehensive and precise than the Park test. We performed the White test with the null hypothesis 𝐻0: 𝛼1 = 𝛼2 = ⋯ = 𝛼90 = 0 against the alternative hypothesis 𝐻 𝑎: 𝑎𝑡 𝑙𝑒𝑎𝑠𝑡 𝑜𝑛𝑒 𝑜𝑓 𝑡ℎ𝑒 𝛼 𝑣𝑎𝑙𝑢𝑒𝑠 𝑖𝑠 𝑛𝑜𝑡 𝑒𝑞𝑢𝑎𝑙 𝑡𝑜 𝑧𝑒𝑟𝑜, and we obtain a statistic equal to 𝑜𝑏𝑠 ∗ 𝑅2 = 268 ∗ 𝑅2 = 131.2916, which is larger than the critical value which is 𝜒90 2 (0.05) = 113.145. This result means that we must reject the White Test at a significance level of 5%, which leads us to conclude that there is heteroskedasticity in our current model. To fix the heteroskedasticity, we must adjust the Standard Errors of each errorterm to account for it. It shows the Standard Errors for coefficients decreased after our adjustment (Figure 5). Now that we have adjusted our model for heteroskedasticity, we can be confident that we have found a model for ROUNDS that has homoscedasticity. To be sure that this model is realistic and logical, we must verify that the respective signs and magnitudes of the coefficients for each characteristic match our initial intuition. The first thing we notice is that the coefficient for FEE is positive, which contradicts both our intuition and the law of demand. For the purposes of our analysis, we are only concerned with the demand model pertaining to the MGS courses. In terms of our analysis, this means that we only care about the condition of the model in which 𝑚𝑔𝑠 = 1. Under this condition, the total effect of FEE
  • 5. on ROUNDS is always negative because the coefficient corresponding to MGS*FEE (which is calculated to be -337.5988) offsets the positive effect of FEE on ROUNDS ( 𝛽 𝐹𝐸𝐸 + 𝛽 𝐹𝐸𝐸∗𝑀𝐺𝑆 < 0) . The coefficient of FEESUB is consistent with our intuition, and shows a positive relationship between the fee charged by other courses and the demand for a specific course. This is also in correspondence the effect of the price of a substitute on demand in economic theory. The coefficient of RATING is also positive, which matches our intuition, which was that the courses with higher ratings in terms of difficulty would attract better golfers, but not necessarily detract golfers with less skill. On the other hand, the negative coefficient in front of SLOPE matches our intuition because less skilled golfers would prefer a course with less hills, but remain ambivalent about the rating. WINTER has a negative relationship with ROUNDS, and the coefficient in front of WINTER has a very large magnitude (𝛽 𝑊𝐼𝑁𝑇𝐸𝑅 =-1586.647), which matches our intuition as well because days are shorter during the winter, and so there are less available tee times, in addition, the weather conditions are not as favorable. We estimated that RAIN is a more important factor than TEMP. RAIN has a bigger absolute coefficient value than TEMP has, which makes sense because even the temperature was comfortable for golfing, people still would be less likely to go golfing if it was rainy. With regards to the effects of TEMP, we would expect positive correlation with ROUNDS because golf is generally more popular in areas with warmer climates. Finally, the coefficients of CART*WINTER and DISTANCE interpret that people would go to the golf course with cart path more, and have less preferences on the courses which are further from Seattle. Besides, each variable has a small (significant) p value, and the sign of each coefficient is reasonable and logical. Also, the adjusted R squared value increased to 𝑅̅2 =0.865925 which is higher than 0.864380, the previous value it had
  • 6. in the unrestricted model. Now that we have verified that the implications of our model hold true in terms of logic and intuition, we can conclude that this model (figure 5) provides the best linear unbiased estimates. Based on this restricted model, we can provide some consulting advice to MGS regarding the structure of their greens fees, specifically in the winter months. We calculated the price elasticity of demand for MGS golf courses during winter and non- winter time to determine if MGS should implement the seasonal rate. We calculated the price elasticity of demand in wintertime (WINTER=1) to be 𝜂 = −2.220695 , and 𝜂 = −0.546797 as the price elasticity of demand during non-winter time (WINTER=0). Since (-2.220695)<-1, it tells us that it is elastic during winter, which means a small change in price causes a larger change in quantity. Also, the price elasticity of demand in winter is more elastic than the one in non-winter time because |-2.220695|>|-0.546797|. According to this result, we recommend MGS to use seasonal rates, specifically by lowering their greens fees in the winter. Since 𝑇𝑜𝑡𝑎𝑙 𝑅𝑒𝑣𝑒𝑛𝑢𝑒 = 𝑇𝑅 = 𝑃 ∗ 𝑄 = 𝐹𝐸𝐸 ∗ 𝑅𝑂𝑈𝑁𝐷𝑆, if the price elasticity of demand is elastic, we can increase the total revue by decreasing the value of FEE. Specifically, MGS will maximize their revenue, and therefore their profits, by lowering their winter-time greens fees to $12.20 (complete derivation in appendix B). To consider whether to build the cart path or the driving range first, we go back to look at the unrestricted model since it includes both CART*WINTER and RANGE. We found CART*WINTER has much larger coefficient value than RANGE, so this means cart has larger impact on increasing ROUNDS than driving range. Therefore, we suggest MGS to fund the paving of cart paths first.
  • 7. Appendix A Figure 1 Unrestricted Model
  • 8. Figure 2 Wald Test (F-test)
  • 10. Figure 4 White Test (Heteroskedasticity) ... (omission of extraneous data)…
  • 11. Figure 5 Best Fit Model
  • 12. Appendix B Derivation of the Profit-Maximizing Fee during the Winter: 𝑁𝑂𝑇𝐸: 𝑡ℎ𝑟𝑜𝑢𝑔ℎ𝑜𝑢𝑡 𝑡ℎ𝑖𝑠 𝑑𝑒𝑟𝑖𝑣𝑎𝑡𝑖𝑜𝑛, 𝑎𝑠𝑠𝑢𝑚𝑒 𝐹𝐸𝐸 = 𝑝, 𝑎𝑛𝑑 𝑅𝑂𝑈𝑁𝐷𝑆( 𝐹𝐸𝐸) = 𝑞( 𝑝) 𝑃𝑟𝑜𝑓𝑖𝑡 = 𝜋( 𝑝) = 𝑇𝑅( 𝑝) − 𝑇𝐶 = 𝑇𝑅( 𝑝), 𝑠𝑖𝑛𝑐𝑒 𝑇𝐶 = 0 𝑇𝑜𝑡𝑎𝑙 𝑅𝑒𝑣𝑒𝑛𝑢𝑒 = 𝑇𝑅( 𝑝) = [ 𝑞( 𝑝)]∙ 𝑝 𝑞( 𝑝) = 𝛽0 − 𝛽1 𝑝 − 𝛽2 𝑝2 𝜋( 𝑝) = 𝑇𝑅( 𝑝) = [ 𝛽0 − 𝛽1 𝑝 − 𝛽2 𝑝2] ∙ 𝑝 = 𝛽0 𝑝 − 𝛽1 𝑝2 − 𝛽2 𝑝3 𝑚𝑎𝑥 {𝑝} [ 𝜋( 𝑝)]: 𝜕 𝜕𝑝 [ 𝜋( 𝑝∗)] = 0, 𝜕2 𝜕𝑝2 [ 𝜋( 𝑝∗)] < 0 𝜕 𝜕𝑝 [ 𝜋( 𝑝)] = 𝛽0 − 2𝛽1 𝑝 − 3𝛽2 𝑝2 = 0 𝑝 = −2𝛽1 ± √(2𝛽1)2 − 4(3𝛽2)(−𝛽0) 2(3𝛽2) = −𝛽1 (3𝛽2) ± √(2𝛽1)2 − 4(3𝛽2)(−𝛽0) 2(3𝛽2) 𝜕2 𝜕𝑝2 [ 𝜋( 𝑝)] = −2𝛽1 − 6𝛽2 𝑝 < 0 𝑝∗ > −𝛽1 (3𝛽2) so: 𝑝∗ = −𝛽1 (3𝛽2) + √(2𝛽1)2 − 4(3𝛽2)(−𝛽0) 2(3𝛽2) by estimating 𝛽0, 𝛽1, 𝑎𝑛𝑑 𝛽2 with our regression coefficients (and average values of input variables held constant) we find that: 𝑝∗ = $12.20