Successfully reported this slideshow.
Your SlideShare is downloading. ×

Fiscal rules and the Sovereign default premium

Ad
Ad
Ad
Ad
Ad
Ad
Ad
Ad
Ad
Ad
Ad
Loading in …3
×

Check these out next

1 of 53 Ad

More Related Content

Slideshows for you (20)

Similar to Fiscal rules and the Sovereign default premium (20)

Advertisement

More from ADEMU_Project (20)

Recently uploaded (20)

Advertisement

Fiscal rules and the Sovereign default premium

  1. 1. Fiscal Rules and the Sovereign Default Premium Juan Carlos Hatchondo Leonardo Martinez Francisco Roch The views expressed herein are those of the authors and should not be attributed to the IMF, its Executive Board, or its management. 1 / 83
  2. 2. ...1 Motivation 2 / 83
  3. 3. FISCAL ANCHORS Fiscal policy frameworks do not have an anchor to manage expectations about future policies (unlike frameworks used for monetary analysis; Leeper 2010). This paper: Having a fiscal anchor could be important. The sovereign spread (and not the debt level) should be the anchor. ...1 Better common anchor (SGP). ...2 More robust anchor/policy advice (Spain?). ...3 Better ownership/more credible/easier to commit too. 3 / 83
  4. 4. FISCAL RULES COULD PROVIDE FISCAL ANCHORS A large and increasing number of countries have fiscal rules with numerical targets. 1985 1986 1987 1988 1989 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 0 10 20 30 40 50 60 70 80 90 Numberofcountrieswithfiscalrules 4 / 83
  5. 5. MOST FISCAL RULES TARGET DEBT LEVELS 1985 1987 1989 1991 1993 1995 1999 2001 2003 2005 2007 2009 2010 2012 2014 Numberofcountrieswithfiscalrules 0 20 40 60 80 Debt rule No debt rule and budget balance rule No debt rule and no budget balance rule 5 / 83
  6. 6. WHAT IS THE OPTIMAL DEBT LEVEL? Blanchard (IMFdirect 2011): “Are old rules of thumb, such as trying to keep the debt-to-GDP ratio below 60 percent in advanced countries, still reliable?” The Fiscal Monitor (2013): “The optimal-debt concept has remained at a fairly abstract level... adjustment needs scenario has used benchmark debt ratios of 60 percent of GDP... But the appropriate debt target need not be the same for all countries...” Eberhardt and Presbitero (JIE 2015): impossibility of finding common debt thresholds across countries for the relationship between debt levels and long-run growth. 6 / 83
  7. 7. DEBT INTOLERANCE USAGBRAUT BEL DNK FRA DEU ITA NLDNOR SWE JPNFIN ISL IRL MLT PRT ESP TUR NZL ZAF BRA CHL COL CRI DOM SLV GTM MEX PANPER URY JAM BHR CYP IRQ ISR LBN QAT HKG IDN KOR MYS PHL SGP THA MAR TUN KAZ BGR RUS CHN UKR CZESVK EST LVA SRB HUN LTU HRV SVN POL ROM 0200400600 SovereignCDSspread(2015),bps 0 50 100 150 200 250 Public debt (2015), % GDP More debt intolerance ⇒ higher spreads for lower debt (Reinhart et al., 2003). 7 / 83
  8. 8. A COMMON, ROBUST, AND CREDIBLE ANCHOR ...1 Political constraints lead to common fiscal anchors for several governments (e.g. SGP) that may face different levels of debt intolerance. ...2 For one government, the level of debt intolerance changes over time and is difficult to identify. What is the debt level consistent with acceptable fiscal risk in Greece? Brazil? Spain? We would like policy advice to be robust to this uncertainty. ...3 The anchor should be credible: governments would not gain from deviating from the fiscal rule. 8 / 83
  9. 9. SPREAD BRAKE VS. DEBT BRAKE A spread (debt) brake imposes a limit on the fiscal balance when the sovereign spread (debt) is above a threshold. 9 / 83
  10. 10. ...2 Three-period model 10 / 83
  11. 11. ENVIRONMENT Government’s income in period t = yt. With t ∈ {1, 2, 3}. y1 = y2 = 0, y3 > 0 and stochastic. The government maximizes utility of a representative consumer. A bond issued at t = 1 promises the payment sequence {δ, 1 − δ}. A bond issued at t = 2 promises a payment of 1 at t = 3. Foreign risk-neutral lenders’ discount factor = 1. Lenders are atomistic and bond market is competitive. Cost of defaulting: Lose fraction ϕ of y3 (no default in first two periods) 11 / 83
  12. 12. OPTIMAL POLICIES Ramsey policies: sequence of borrowing that maximizes the government’s expected utility in period 1, given the default rule of the period 3 government. Markov policies: sequence of borrowing chosen sequentially by the governments in periods 1 and 2. 12 / 83
  13. 13. (WITH LONG-TERM DEBT) WE NEED A FISCAL RULE . Proposition .. ...... Suppose δ < 1; i.e., the government issues long-term debt in period 1. Then, only with a fiscal rule limiting the government’s choices in period 2, Markov policies coincide with Ramsey policies. 13 / 83
  14. 14. WHY IS A FISCAL RULE NEEDED? The period 2 Ramsey policy satisfies u′ ( c2(bR 1 , bR 2 ) ) [ q2(bR 1 , bR 2 ) + bR 2 ∂q2(bR 1 , bR 2 ) ∂b2 ] = βE [ u′ ( c3(bR 1 , bR 2 , y3) ) [ 1 − ˆd(bR 1 , bR 2 , y3) ]] −u′ ( c1(bR 1 , bR 2 ) ) bR 1 ∂q1(bR 1 , bR 2 ) ∂b2 . But the period 2 Markov strategy satisfies u′ ( c2(b1, bM 2 (b1)) ) [ q2(b1, bM 2 (b1)) + bM 2 (b1) ∂q2(b1, bM 2 (b1)) ∂b2 ] = βE [ u′ ( c3(b1, bM 2 (b1), y3) ) [ 1 − ˆd(b1, bM 2 (b1), y3) ]] . 14 / 83
  15. 15. IDIOSYNCRATIC DEBT BRAKE = IDIOSYNCRATIC SPREAD BRAKE Idiosyncratic debt brake imposes a ceiling on the debt level, (1 − δ)b1 + b2 ≤ ¯b. Idiosyncratic spread brake imposes a ceiling on the spread paid by the government and thus a floor on the sovereign bond price, q2(b1, b2) ≥ q. . Proposition .. ...... If the government’s choices in period 2 are limited with either a debt brake with threshold ¯b∗ = (1 − δ)bR 1 + bR 2 or a spread brake with threshold q∗ = q2(bR 1 , bR 2 ), Markov policies coincide with Ramsey policies. 15 / 83
  16. 16. OPTIMAL “COMMON” FISCAL RULES Consider a set of heterogenous economies indexed by the value of the parameter θ ∈ {ϕ, σy, β}. v(x; θ) = expected utility in period 1 of an economy with a fiscal rule with threshold x. h(θ) = density function for θ in the set. The optimal common fiscal rule threshold X∗ maximizes max x ∫ v(x; θ)h(θ)dθ. 16 / 83
  17. 17. WHY A “COMMON AND ROBUST” FISCAL RULE? X∗ would be chosen by a planner that maximizes the expected utility in period 1 of ...1 a set of different economies while giving weight h(θ) to economies with parameter value θ. ...2 a single economy when the planner is uncertain about the value of the parameter θ and assigns the likelihood h(θ) to θ. 17 / 83
  18. 18. ASSUMPTION 1 The function ζq(b) = b ϕ f ( b ϕ ) 1 − F ( b ϕ ) is increasing with respect to b and limb→∞ ζq(b) ≥ 1. 18 / 83
  19. 19. COMMON SPREAD BRAKE ≻ COMMON DEBT BRAKE . Proposition .. ...... Suppose δ = 0, u(c) = c, and Assumption 1 holds. Then, for any economy with cost of defaulting ϕ, the optimal debt brake threshold is ¯b∗ = ηϕ and the optimal spread brake threshold is q∗ = 1 − F(η), with η > 0. Therefore, for any set of economies that differ in the level of debt intolerance (i.e., for economies with different values of ϕ), the optimal common spread-brake threshold is Q∗ = 1 − F(η), and generates larger welfare gains than any common debt-brake threshold ¯B. 19 / 83
  20. 20. NUMERICAL EXAMPLE Assume: u (c) = −c−1 β = 1, log(y3) ∼ N ( 0, σy ) , δ = 0. If σy = 0.1, debt levels between 25 and 169 percent of average period 3 income, spreads between 1 and 12 percent. 20 / 83
  21. 21. WELFARE GAINS FROM IDIOSYNCRATIC RULE 0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1 Default cost (φ) 0 0.5 1 1.5 2 Welfaregain(%cons.) Idiosyncratic rule 0 5 10 15 0 0.5 1 1.5 2 Std deviation of income (in %) Welfaregain(%cons.) Idiosyncratic rule Same welfare gains with either optimal idiosyncratic debt brake or optimal idiosyncratic spread brake 21 / 83
  22. 22. COMMON DEBT BRAKE DOESN’T WORK WELL 0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1 Default cost (φ) 0 0.5 1 1.5 2 Welfaregain(%cons.) Idiosyncratic rule Common debt brake 0 5 10 15 0 0.5 1 1.5 2 Std deviation of income (in %) Welfaregain(%cons.) Idiosyncratic rule Common debt brake The optimal common debt brake does not impose an excessive constraint in low-debt-intolerance economies and thus is not binding in most economies. 22 / 83
  23. 23. COMMON SPREAD BRAKE IS BETTER 0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1 Default cost (φ) 0 0.5 1 1.5 2 Welfaregain(%cons.) Idiosyncratic rule Common debt brake Common spread brake 0 5 10 15 0 0.5 1 1.5 2 Std deviation of income (in %) Welfaregain(%cons.) Idiosyncratic rule Common debt brake Common spread brake A relatively low spread threshold still does not impose an excessive constraint in low-debt-intolerance economies but imposes a welfare improving constraint in high-debt-intolerance economies. 23 / 83
  24. 24. ...3 Quantitative model 24 / 83
  25. 25. LITERATURE Eaton and Gersovitz (RESTUD 1981), Aguiar and Gopinath (JIE 2006), Arellano (AER 2008), Hatchondo and Martinez (JIE 2009, EQ 2012, IEJ 2013), Hatchondo, Martinez, and Sosa-Padilla (JME 2014, JPE 2016), Hatchondo, Martinez, and Onder (JIE 2017), Hatchondo, Martinez, and Sapriza (EQ 2007, IER 2009, RED 2010), Arellano and Ramanarayanan (JPE 2012), Chatterjee and Eyigungor (AER 2012, AER 2016), Cuadra and Sapriza (JIE 2008), Cuadra, Sanchez, and Sapriza (RED 2010), Boz (JIE 2011), Durdu, Nunes, and Sapriza (JIE 2013). 25 / 83
  26. 26. ...1 The no-rule environment 26 / 83
  27. 27. EQUILIBRIUM CONCEPT Markov Perfect Equilibrium. Each period the government decides taking as given bond prices and future defaulting, spending, taxing, and borrowing strategies. Current optimal choices are consistent with future government strategies. Bond holders make zero expected profits. Limit of finite-horizon economy. 27 / 83
  28. 28. TECHNOLOGY Linear technology in labor y = ez l TFP shock z follows a Markov process. 28 / 83
  29. 29. PREFERENCES Benevolent government max Et [ ∞ ∑ j=0 βj u ( ct+j, gt+j, lt+j ) ] taking into account private consumption and labor decisions. g =public consumption. 29 / 83
  30. 30. IF THE GOVERNMENT PAYS ITS DEBT OBLIGATIONS Issues long-term debt. Bonds are perpetuities with geometrically decreasing coupon obligations Important for the quantitative performance of the model (Hatchondo and Martinez 2009; Chatterjee and Eyigungor 2012). Chooses provision of public good: g Chooses labor tax: τ 30 / 83
  31. 31. DEFAULTS Two costs of defaulting: ...1 Exclusion from credit market for a stochastic number of periods. ...2 Fall in TFP in every period in which the government is in default. With constant probability, the government can exit the default by exchanging α new bonds per bond in default (debt restructuring). 1 − α = haircut Chooses g and labor tax τ while in default. 31 / 83
  32. 32. LENDERS Foreign. Risk-neutral (later, same results with shock to the lenders’ risk aversion) Opportunity cost of lending: risk-free bonds paying r. 32 / 83
  33. 33. SIMULATIONS MATCH TARGETS Data No-rule benchmark Mean debt-to-income ratio (in %) 61.8 61.5 Debt duration (years) 6.0 6.0 Annual spread (in %) 2.0 2.0 Mean g/c (in %) 36.5 36.5 σ(g)/σ(y) 0.9 0.9 σ(c)/σ(y) 1.1 1.1 33 / 83
  34. 34. ...5 Fiscal rules 34 / 83
  35. 35. DEBT BRAKE b′ ≤ max{¯b, (1 − δ)b} Find the optimal value for ¯b. 35 / 83
  36. 36. SPREAD BRAKE Find the optimal value for q in the constraint under repayment: q(b′ , z) Price at which bonds are issued ≥ q if b′ > b. 36 / 83
  37. 37. ...6 Quantitative results 37 / 83
  38. 38. IDIOSYNCRATIC DEBT BRAKE ≃ IDIOSYNCRATIC SPREAD BRAKE Without rule Debt brake Spread brake (52.5%) (0.45%) Mean debt-to-income ratio 61.5 54.9 59.4 Annual spread (in %) 2.0 0.5 1.0 Mean g/c (in %) 36.5 37.1 36.9 σ(g)/σ(y) 0.9 0.9 1.0 σ(c)/σ(y) 1.1 1.1 1.1 Defaults per 100 years 2.9 0.8 1.1 Welfare gain (in %) 0.5 0.4 38 / 83
  39. 39. BORROWING WITHOUT A FISCAL ANCHOR 0 10 20 30 40 50 60 70 End-of-period debt / GDP (in %) 0 0.5 1 1.5 2 2.5 3 Annualspread(in%) Without rules 0 10 20 30 40 50 60 70 End-of-period debt / GDP (in %) 0 10 20 30 40 50 60 Debtmarketvalue/GDP(in%) Without rules 39 / 83
  40. 40. BORROWING WITH A FISCAL ANCHOR The fiscal anchor allow for less debt (lower face value) but may allow for more borrowing (because of the higher interest rate) 0 10 20 30 40 50 60 70 End-of-period debt / GDP (in %) 0 0.5 1 1.5 2 2.5 3 Annualspread(in%) Without rules With optimal spread brake 0 10 20 30 40 50 60 70 End-of-period debt / GDP (in %) 0 10 20 30 40 50 60 Debtmarketvalue/GDP(in%) Without rules With optimal spread brake 40 / 83
  41. 41. NEGATIVE SHOCKS WITHOUT A FISCAL ANCHOR Quarter 0 20 40 60 80 % -10 -5 0 5 10 15 20 LogTFP Spread without rule 41 / 83
  42. 42. NEGATIVE SHOCK WITH A FISCAL ANCHOR Quarter 0 20 40 60 80 % -10 -5 0 5 10 15 20 LogTFP Spread without rule Spread with optimal spread brake 42 / 83
  43. 43. CONSUMPTION IS NOT MORE VOLATILE WITH THE SPREAD BRAKE Quarter 0 20 40 60 80 % -10 -5 0 5 10 15 20 LogTFP Spread without rule Spread with optimal spread brake 0 10 20 30 40 50 60 70 80 Quarter 20 30 40 50 60 70 80 90 % -5 0 5 10 15 % Log private consumption without rule Log private consumption with optimal spread brake Log public consumption without rule Log public consumption with optimal spread brake Debt without rule Debt with optimal spread brake 43 / 83
  44. 44. COMMON RULES Longer exclusion ⇒ ↑ cost of defaulting ⇒ more debt. Higher recovery ⇒ ↓ benefit of defaulting ⇒ more debt. More impatient borrower ⇒ ↑ benefit of borrowing ⇒ more debt. We assume exclusions between 1 and 5 years (benchmark = 3), recovery rates between 10% and 60% (benchmark = 35%), and discount factor between 0.96 and 0.985 (benchmark = 0.97). Thus, we study economies with average debt levels between 30% and 90%, and average spreads between 0.5% and 5.5%. 44 / 83
  45. 45. HETEROGENOUS ECONOMIES 1 2 3 4 5 Exclusion duration (years) 20 30 40 50 60 70 80 Debtas%oftrendGDP Avg. debt without rules 1 2 3 4 5 Exclusion duration (years) 0 0.5 1 1.5 2 2.5 3 3.5 4 Annualspread(in%) Avg. spread without rules 45 / 83
  46. 46. OPTIMAL IDIOSYNCRATIC THRESHOLDS 1 2 3 4 5 Exclusion duration (years) 20 30 40 50 60 70 80 Debtas%oftrendGDP Avg. debt without rules Optimal idiosyncratic debt threshold 1 2 3 4 5 Exclusion duration (years) 0 0.5 1 1.5 2 2.5 3 3.5 4 Annualspread(in%) Avg. spread without rules Optimal idiosyncratic spread threshold The optimal idiosyncratic debt threshold changes almost one to one with the average debt level in the no-rule economy. 46 / 83
  47. 47. RAWLSIAN DEBT BRAKE GENERATES WELFARE LOSSES 1 2 3 4 5 Exclusion duration (years) -1.5 -1 -0.5 0 0.5 Welfaregain(%CE) Optimal common debt brake 0.1 0.2 0.3 0.4 0.5 0.6 Recovery rate -0.5 0 0.5 Welfaregain(%CE) Optimal common debt brake To be binding in high-debt-intolerance economies, the optimal common Rawlsian debt brake imposes an excessive constraint in low-debt-intolerance economies. 47 / 83
  48. 48. RAWLSIAN SPREAD BRAKE ≻ RAWLSIAN DEBT BRAKE 1 2 3 4 5 −1.4 −1.2 −1 −0.8 −0.6 −0.4 −0.2 0 0.2 0.4 Exclusion duration (years) Welfaregain(%CE) Optimal common debt brake Optimal common spread brake 0.1 0.2 0.3 0.4 0.5 0.6 −0.8 −0.6 −0.4 −0.2 0 0.2 0.4 Recovery rateWelfaregain(%CE) Optimal common debt brake Optimal common spread brake The optimal common Rawlsian spread brake is binding in high-debt-intolerance economies without imposing an excessive constraint in low-debt-intolerance economies. 48 / 83
  49. 49. PENALTY NEEDED TO ENFORCE THE RAWLSIAN DEBT BRAKE 1 2 3 4 5 Exclusion duration (years) -5 0 5 10 15 20 25 Enforcementcost(%oftrendGDP) Rawlsian debt brake 49 / 83
  50. 50. PENALTY NEEDED TO ENFORCE THE RAWLSIAN SPREAD BRAKE 1 2 3 4 5 −5 0 5 10 15 20 25 Exclusion duration (years) Enforcementcost(%oftrendGDP) Rawlsian debt brake Rawlsian spread brake 50 / 83
  51. 51. ...7 Conclusions and extensions 51 / 83
  52. 52. CONCLUSIONS Maybe sovereign spreads should play a more prominent role in anchoring discussions of fiscal policy Economies that suffer less debt intolerance should be allowed to issue more debt. It may be much easier to enforce a spread brake than to enforce a debt brake. Also a market-determined fiscal anchor could be less susceptible to creative accounting more comprehensive measure of fiscal risks (e.g., debt maturity, currency composition, implicit or contingent liabilities) 52 / 83
  53. 53. NEED FOR FUTURE WORK? What should the spread-brake threshold be? Should it be reduced gradually (mimicking disinflation periods)? Which interest rates should fiscal rules use? The average spread over which period should be used to trigger the spread brake? How should a spread brake be complemented with other numerical targets? How fast should the fiscal adjustment triggered by the brake be? Would the spread limit help with other shocks (bailout probability, multiple equilibria, political shocks, debt shocks)? 53 / 83

×